10.10.2014 Views

13th Biennial Meeting - Penn State Law

13th Biennial Meeting - Penn State Law

13th Biennial Meeting - Penn State Law

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

TEXAS Volume 42<br />

INTERNATIONAL Number 3<br />

LAW Summer 2007<br />

JOURNAL<br />

CONTENTS<br />

INTERNATIONAL ACADEMY OF COMMERCIAL AND CONSUMER LAW<br />

CHANGING LAW FOR CHANGING TIMES, 13T BIENNIAL MEETING<br />

IN T R O D U CTIO N ....................................................................................................................... 369<br />

Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW. IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE .................................. 371<br />

Mads Andenas and Stefan Zleptnig<br />

(Comparative <strong>Law</strong>, International Business, and Competition <strong>Law</strong>)<br />

THE MODERNIZATION OF EUROPEAN COMPETITION LAW: A STORY OF<br />

U NFIN ISH ED C O NCEPTS ........................................................................................................ 429<br />

Jirgen Basedow<br />

(International Business, Competition <strong>Law</strong>, and European Union)<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA .......................................................... 441<br />

Stephanie Ben-Ishai<br />

(Comparative <strong>Law</strong> and Corporate)<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION IN UNCITRAL's LEGISLATIVE<br />

G UIDE ON INSOLVENCY LAW ............................................................................................... 475<br />

Susan Block-Lieb and Terence Halliday<br />

(International Business and Insolvency)<br />

PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY<br />

IN E A ST A SIA ........................................................................................................................... 5 15<br />

Douglas W. Arner, Charles D. Booth, Paul Lejot, Berry EC. Hsu<br />

(Comparative <strong>Law</strong>, Legal Institutions, and Secured<br />

Lending/Securitization)<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW: THE<br />

EVOLUTION OF THE D OCTRINE ........................................................................................... 561<br />

James E. Byrne<br />

(Payment Systems)<br />

THEORIZING TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW ......................................................... 597<br />

Ross Cranston<br />

(International Business and Legal Theory)<br />

DEVELOPING A NEW COMMERCIAL COURT IN GHANA .................................................. 619<br />

Kofi Date-Bah<br />

(Legal Institutions)<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. [i] 2006-2007


DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES<br />

FOR THE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY:THE ACCELERATING PACE OF<br />

COMMON AND CIVIL LAW CONVERGENCE ........................................................................ 625<br />

Louis F Del Duca<br />

(Comparative <strong>Law</strong> and Legal Theory)<br />

CANADIAN PREFERENCE LAW REFORM ............................................................................ 661<br />

Anthony Duggan and Thomas G. W Telfer<br />

(Insolvency)<br />

RECENT INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE<br />

INSTRUMENTS AND PAYMENT AND SETTLEMENT SYSTEMS ............................................. 685<br />

Benjamin Geva<br />

(Comparative <strong>Law</strong>, International Business, Payment Systems, and<br />

European Union)<br />

SECURED LENDING AND ITS POVERTY REDUCTION EFFECT ......................................... 727<br />

Boris Kozolchyk<br />

(Comparative <strong>Law</strong> and Secured Lending/Securitization)<br />

SECU RITIZATIO N IN ISRA EL .................................................................................................. 751<br />

Shalom Lerner<br />

(Secured Lending/Securitization)<br />

JAPAN'S PERSONAL INSOLVENCY LAW ................................................................................ 765<br />

Junichi Matsushita<br />

(Insolvency and Consumer <strong>Law</strong>)<br />

THE LANDMARK 2005 HAGUE CONVENTION ON CHOICE OF COURT<br />

A G R E E M E N T S .......................................................................................................................... 773<br />

Ved P Nanda<br />

(International Business)<br />

BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING<br />

ECONOMIES: CREATING AN ACCESSIBLE AND EQUITABLE CONSUMER<br />

BASE FROM THE "E XCLUDED" ............................................................................................ 789<br />

Joseph J. Norton<br />

(Comparative <strong>Law</strong> and Consumer <strong>Law</strong>)<br />

GROUP INSOLVENCIES - SOME THOUGHTS ABOUT NEW APPROACHES ....................... 819<br />

Christoph G. Paulus<br />

(International Business and Insolvency)<br />

LEGAL MERCANTILE EVOLUTION FROM THE TWENTIETH CENTURY TO<br />

THE DAWNING OFTHE TWENTY-FIRST CENTURY ............................................................. 831<br />

Arcelia Quintana-Adriano<br />

(Comparative <strong>Law</strong>)<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW: A COMPARATIVE<br />

LOOK AT THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF MARKET REGULATION ................................... 843<br />

Arie Reich<br />

(Comparative <strong>Law</strong> and Competition <strong>Law</strong>)<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. [ii] 2006-2007


DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT IN GLOBAL CAPITAL<br />

M A R K E T S ................................................................................................................................. 87 5<br />

Janis Sarra<br />

(International Business)<br />

AVOIDANCE OF PRE-BANKRUPTCY TRANSACTIONS IN MULTINATIONAL<br />

B A N K RU PTCY C A SES .............................................................................................................. 899<br />

Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook<br />

(International Business and Insolvency)<br />

THE DISAPPEARING DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND OBLIGATION: THE<br />

IMPACT OFALIGNING LEGAL ANALYSIS AND COMMERCIAL EXPECTATION ................ 917<br />

Sarah Worthington<br />

(Legal Theory)<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. [iii] 2006-2007


HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. [iv] 2006-2007


Introduction<br />

JAY LAWRENCE WESTBROOK*<br />

This issue of the Journal publishes papers presented at the 2006 <strong>Biennial</strong><br />

<strong>Meeting</strong> of the International Academy of Commercial and Consumer <strong>Law</strong>. The<br />

Academy consists of one hundred scholars and teachers from around the world.<br />

Founded in the 1980s, its members come from thirty-three countries. They teach<br />

and write across the entire range of law affecting commerce, including contracts, the<br />

regulation of consumer transactions, banking and finance, market regulation, and<br />

bankruptcy/insolvency. Presiding over the 2006 meeting of the Academy was its<br />

President, Ross Cranston of the London School of Economics (and former Solicitor<br />

General of England). The President Elect was Juirgen Basedow, Director of the Max<br />

Planck Institute for Private International <strong>Law</strong>. The Treasurer was Ron Cuming of<br />

the University of Saskatchewan.<br />

The IACCL meets every other year to discuss papers presented by the<br />

members. These papers report developments in commercial law and law reform<br />

proposals in various countries and international institutions, public and private. The<br />

IACCL has met all over the world, including Oxford University in England, St.<br />

Louis University in the United <strong>State</strong>s, Bar Ilan University in Israel, the Max Planck<br />

Institute in Germany, and the University of Riga in Latvia.<br />

The Journal is publishing twenty-two papers reflecting the eclectic interests of<br />

our group. It would be quite impossible in a short space to describe each of them, so<br />

I will limit myself to describing them by subject, with some mentioned twice in<br />

overlapping categories. The editors have helpfully marked them by the subject areas<br />

below.<br />

Comparative <strong>Law</strong>: Andenas; Ben-Ishai; Booth; Del Duca; Geva; Kozolchyk;<br />

Norton; Quintana-Adriano; Reich.<br />

International Business: Andenas; Basedow; Block-Lieb; Cranston; Geva;<br />

Nanda; Paulus; Sarra; Westbrook.<br />

Legal Theory: Cranston; Del Duca; Worthington.<br />

Legal Institutions: Date-Bah; Booth.<br />

Insolvency: Block-Lieb; Booth; Duggan; Matsushita; Paulus; Westbrook.<br />

Secured Lending/Securitization: Booth; Kozolchyk; Lerner.<br />

Consumer <strong>Law</strong>: Matsushita; Norton.<br />

Competition <strong>Law</strong>: Andenas; Basedow; Reich.<br />

Payment Systems: Byrne; Geva.<br />

Corporate: Ben-Ishai.<br />

Benno C. Schmidt Chair of Business <strong>Law</strong>, The University of Texas School of <strong>Law</strong>.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 369 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:369<br />

European Union: Basedow; Geva.<br />

One of the joys of the Academy's meetings is the presentation of topics in areas<br />

of interest to each of us but just enough outside our specialties that we are<br />

introduced to concepts and developments we might not otherwise have considered.<br />

Nonetheless, one theme dominates throughout these papers: global law reform.<br />

Even developments in national and comparative reports frequently illustrate the<br />

spread of legal tools and concepts, not merely borrowed but re-engineered and<br />

internationalized. In describing this process, some papers are focused on<br />

harmonization or convergence, while others consider conventions and model laws<br />

that are designed to establish international or multinational rules. Nowhere is<br />

reform more active than in attempts to modernize and harmonize the law governing<br />

security interests. No less than five papers reflect a strong commitment to the idea<br />

that sound secured credit laws are important to economic growth and even the<br />

reduction of poverty, with the locus of reform proposals ranging from the<br />

traditionally commercial societies of the European Union to the emerging<br />

commercial giant, China. Insolvency and bankruptcy attracted a number of authors<br />

discussing, inter alia, UNCITRAL's work in insolvency law and the continuing<br />

spread of consumer bankruptcy laws. If one considers, as I do, that security and<br />

bankruptcy are essentially a single topic, nine papers make this one the most<br />

discussed subject.<br />

Competition law also receives considerable attention, including a critique of<br />

EU reform and a look at the special place of agricultural competition, while another<br />

paper considers the concept of proportionality in world trade law. Two papers<br />

discuss international payment systems, the conduit of through which all this global<br />

commerce must flow, and another paper addresses the related topic of disclosure in<br />

international capital markets. Three others address institutional questions, including<br />

the construction of a specialized court, the regularization of choice of forum, and the<br />

evolving concept of the gatekeeper. Three of the papers step back from the<br />

immediate proposals for reform to consider from a wider perspective the rule of law<br />

in the globalization process, harmonization across the civil law/common law<br />

boundary, and the evolving relationship between property and obligation.<br />

Although a number of the papers discuss issues important to consumers, there<br />

are two papers focused specifically on consumer reform in banking and insolvency<br />

law.<br />

These brief descriptions necessarily do no more than hint at the rich potpourri<br />

that we enjoyed during the Academy's meeting in Austin and that awaits the reader<br />

in this issue. Enjoy.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 370 2006-2007


Proportionality:<br />

WTO <strong>Law</strong>: in Comparative Perspective<br />

MADS ANDENAS" AND STEFAN ZLEPTNIG*"<br />

SUMMARY<br />

1. IN T R O D U CTIO N ................................................................................................... 372<br />

II. THE PRINCIPLE OF PROPORTIONALITY ............................................................ 375<br />

A . L egal P rincip les ........................................................................................... 375<br />

1. N ature of Principles .............................................................................. 376<br />

2. Public International <strong>Law</strong> and WTO <strong>Law</strong> .......................................... 379<br />

3 . C o nclusio ns ........................................................................................... 381<br />

B . Introducing Proportionality ....................................................................... 382<br />

C. Test in D ifferent C ontexts ........................................................................... 383<br />

D . Typology of Functions ................................................................................ 384<br />

1. Control and Limitation of Discretion ................................................ 384<br />

2. Balancing of Conflicting Rights and Interests .................................. 385<br />

3. Standard for Judicial Review .............................................................. 385<br />

4. Scope of Legal N orm s .......................................................................... 386<br />

5. Limit and Rationalize the Power of Judges ....................................... 386<br />

6. Political Theories and Proportionality ............................................... 387<br />

E. Different Elements of the Proportionality Test ........................................ 388<br />

1. S u itab ility ............................................................................................... 388<br />

2 . N ecessity ................................................................................................ 389<br />

3. Proportionality Stricto Sensu .............................................................. 390<br />

III. INTENSITY O F R EVIEW ....................................................................................... 392<br />

A. Intensity of Review in EC <strong>Law</strong> .................................................................. 393<br />

B. Standard of Review in WTO <strong>Law</strong> ............................................................ 395<br />

IV. PROPORTIONALITY IN PUBLIC INTERNATIONAL LAW .................................... 398<br />

A . C ounterm easures ......................................................................................... 398<br />

B. Use of Force and Armed Conflicts ............................................................ 400<br />

* Professor of <strong>Law</strong>, University of Leicester; Senior Fellow, Institute of European and Comparative<br />

<strong>Law</strong>, University of Oxford. Email: ma199@le.ac.uk.<br />

** Assistant, Institute of Constitutional and Administrative <strong>Law</strong>, University of Vienna. Email:<br />

stefan.zleptnig@univie.ac.at.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 371 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371i<br />

C. M aritim e D elim itation ................................................................................. 404<br />

D . C o n clusio n ................................................................................................... 404<br />

V. BALANCING IN US CONSTITUTIONAL LAW: THE INTERSTATE<br />

C O M M ERCE C LA U SE ........................................................................................... 404<br />

V I. BALANCING IN THE W TO .................................................................................. 408<br />

A. Objective Justifications: Public Policy Exceptions in the GA TT ............ 408<br />

1. Introduction .......................................................................................... 408<br />

2. G eneral D esign ..................................................................................... 409<br />

i. N ecessary to ................................................<br />

410<br />

ii. R elatin g to ...................................................................................... 4 12<br />

3. Application of the Measure: The Chapeau ....................................... 413<br />

3. Conclusion: How the Tests in Article XX GATT Operate ............. 415<br />

B. Positive Obligations for Domestic Regulation .......................................... 416<br />

1. SPS A greem ent ..................................................................................... 416<br />

2. T B T A greem ent ................................................................................... 421<br />

3. Conclusion: How the Tests in the SPS and TBT Agreements<br />

O p erate .......................................................<br />

423<br />

V II. C O N CLU SIO N ....................................................................................................... 424<br />

I. INTRODUCTION<br />

Proportionality, necessity and balancing are discussed in the context of the<br />

World Trade Organization (WTO). We find these tests at prominent places in the<br />

GATS and the GATT, as well as in the Agreement on the Application of Sanitary<br />

and Phytosanitary Measures (SPS Agreement) and the Agreement on Technical<br />

Barriers to Trade (TBT Agreement). The meaning of these tests and their<br />

interrelationship is not always clear. There is considerable controversy among<br />

participants at the diplomatic, policy, treaty-making, or the dispute settlement level,<br />

who put different meanings into the different tests and concepts. The discussion<br />

among scholars is often influenced by a projection of national meanings and<br />

discourses in the WTO and GATS context.<br />

The liberalisation of trade in goods and services requires that the meaning of<br />

and the relationship between these tests are clarified. In this article we set out a<br />

comparative approach for doing so at a general WTO level, but this approach is<br />

particularly relevant in the context of the GATS and the liberalisation of trade in<br />

services.<br />

In the WTO, as in any other legal and political system, value choices are<br />

reflected in the legal order. The fundamental question in this respect is which<br />

institution should be competent to make those choices and how this should be done.'<br />

It may be that this is a task for the legislator, the courts, or for both.<br />

1. See generally Joel Trachtman, Trade and... Problems, Cost-Benefit Analysis and Subsidiarity, 9<br />

EUR. J. INT'L L. 32 (1998).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 372 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

In those cases where courts and tribunals review the actions of other bodies,<br />

they usually face value choices in many different ways. That applies to the review of<br />

legislation and administrative action in domestic law. It also applies to the review of<br />

the compliance of states with international law obligations. The legal solutions and<br />

techniques for dealing with these issues will often be similar, but there is also<br />

considerable variation.<br />

Our focus is on the role of proportionality and balancing in the dispute<br />

settlement system of the WTO. Proportionality is a prominent legal principle in<br />

many legal orders, and all legal systems have to undertake different forms of<br />

balancing, both in determining the content of rules and in their application<br />

Proportionality has a major impact at the national level, in federal-type legal<br />

systems, and in international law. It also serves to control the discretion exercised by<br />

domestic authorities and to limit the interference with, or the restriction of,<br />

individual rights of citizens. It is a key legal concept to assist with the trading-off of<br />

competing values. These issues also arise in the context of WTO law, particularly in<br />

the context of the reconciliation of trade and non-trade issues.<br />

WTO lawyers have discussed the role of the principle of proportionality in the<br />

WTO legal order for several years. In 2001, Axel Desmedt published a rather full<br />

analysis in an article on proportionality in WTO law, and there have been a<br />

considerable number of other publications dealing with the same or related issues.'<br />

Desmedt's overall conclusion is that there is "not one single overarching (unwritten)<br />

proportionality principle in WTO law."' Other authors have similarly concluded that<br />

there is neither a general proportionality requirement in WTO law, nor has such a<br />

general test been applied by the WTO tribunals. The main argument advanced<br />

against proportionality is that the WTO is institutionally not ready for such a<br />

fundamental balancing of values and interests (mainly economic versus noneconomic),<br />

and that such balancing is at the core of the proportionality analysis.<br />

Marceau and Trachtman point to some additional reasons for skepticism against<br />

balancing and proportionality in the WTO:<br />

To many commentators, the idea of balancing tests in contexts where<br />

domestic regulation is subject to international scrutiny has been anathema<br />

to judicial restraint and national sovereignty .... There are two likely<br />

reasons. First, balancing tests seem to some to accord too much power to<br />

courts. However, it is not unusual for courts to be assigned the task of<br />

balancing, explicitly or implicitly, under specified circumstances ...<br />

Second, balancing tests seem to intervene too greatly in national<br />

regulatory autonomy. 6<br />

2. See discussion infra Part II.<br />

3. Axel Desmedt, Proportionality in WTO <strong>Law</strong>, 4 J. INT'L ECON. L. 441, 441-480 (2001); Id. at 478<br />

(arguing that "it seems that there is no basis yet for the recognition in WTO law of an unwritten and<br />

overarching proportionality principle as known in EC law.").<br />

4. Id.<br />

5. Jan Neumann & Elisabeth TUrk, Necessity Revisited: Proportionality in World Trade Organization<br />

<strong>Law</strong> after Korea-Beef EC-Asbestos and EC- Sardines, 37 J. WORLD TRADE 199, 231-33 (2003).<br />

6. Gabrielle Marceau & Joel Trachtman. The Technical Barriers to Trade Agreement, the Sanitary and<br />

Phytosanitary Measures Agreement, and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade: A Map of the World<br />

Trade Organization <strong>Law</strong> of Domestic Regulation of Goods, 36 J. WORLD TRADE 811, 850-51 (2002).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 373 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

In contrast, Meinhard Hilf has argued in his writing that "the principle of<br />

proportionality is one of the more basic principles underlying the multilateral trading<br />

system.", 7 The author emphasizes that a "sensitive balancing process, guided by the<br />

principle of proportionality . ..is needed in which no rule or principle involved<br />

should be left to redundancy or inutility. The principle of proportionality should<br />

govern any process of interpretation and application of WTO law with a view to<br />

obtaining a due relation between the different interests at stake." 8<br />

This disagreement in academic writing is the background against which this<br />

article is situated. We attempt to explore whether the disagreement is a matter of<br />

semantics or whether it impacts more fundamental issues of the WTO legal order. It<br />

could be argued that it does not really matter whether one refers to a particular legal<br />

phenomenon as "proportionality" if different terms ultimately bear the same<br />

meaning. This is a challenge regularly faced by comparative law scholars, namely<br />

that "[a]pparently identical words may have a different meaning and apparently<br />

different words may have the same meaning. '<br />

The fundamental question which we address in this article is how comparative<br />

legal thinking about the principle of proportionality and other balancing tests can<br />

help explore some of the most challenging questions of WTO law. One core<br />

challenge is the balancing of competing values and interests in the WTO. Another<br />

challenge is the degree of international constraint imposed on domestic regulation.<br />

This leads to the questions of how much deference international organizations and<br />

their judicial bodies do show towards sovereign WTO Members, and how much they<br />

should show.<br />

Our analysis is informed by insights from domestic constitutional law, legal<br />

theory, the law of human rights, European law, public international law, and WTO<br />

law. We attempt to provide a conceptual framework to analyze how balancing and<br />

proportionality are made to work in the law of the WTO and the dispute settlement<br />

process.<br />

Our main conclusion is that there is no crude balancing of trade and non-trade<br />

values and interests in the WTO. The tests written into the WTO Agreements<br />

provide for a more sophisticated way of balancing, taking account of the individual<br />

circumstances at stake, and the competing rights and interests involved. We argue<br />

that comparative legal thinking based on insights gained from the principle of<br />

proportionality, and the role of principles generally, may help structure and<br />

rationalize this process.<br />

In this article, we proceed as follows. In Chapter II, we first discuss the nature<br />

of legal principles from a theoretical perspective and how this may influence the<br />

thinking about balancing in WTO law. We then discuss the role of principles in<br />

public international law and WTO law, providing a background for the subsequent<br />

discussion of the principle of proportionality. The latter parts of Chapter II deal<br />

with the principle of proportionality in a comparative context. We identify its core<br />

functions and elements to carve out its essential characteristics. In Chapter III, we<br />

discuss the interaction between the principle of proportionality and the concept of<br />

7. Meinhard Hilf, Power, Rules and Principles- Which Orientation for WTO/GA TT <strong>Law</strong>?, 4 J. INT'L<br />

ECON. L. 111, 120 (2001).<br />

8. Id. at 130.<br />

9. Mark Van Hoecke, Deep Level Comparative <strong>Law</strong> 10-11, (Eur. Univ. Inst. Working Paper LAW<br />

No. 2002/13), available at http:l/cadmus.iue.it/dspacelbitstreamll814/191/lllawO2-13.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 374 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

standard (or intensity) of review. We argue that these concepts, which are often<br />

treated separately, need to be assessed jointly to gain a fuller understanding of (a)<br />

judicial review generally and (b) the principle of proportionality as applied as a test<br />

of review. Proportionality is also a core principle in public international law. For<br />

this reason, we explore its main characteristics in Chapter IV to assess its possible<br />

impact on WTO law. In Chapter V, we explore the necessity and balancing tests of<br />

U.S. constitutional law. We then assess the different balancing tests in WTO law in<br />

Chapter VI. We focus on the tests under Article XX GATT and in the SPS and TBT<br />

Agreements. Our analysis of those tests is informed by the preceding discussion of<br />

the main features of the principle of proportionality in different contexts. Finally,<br />

we draw some conclusions and offer some suggestions for a better understanding of<br />

the balancing undertaken by the judicial bodies of the WTO.<br />

II.<br />

THE PRINCIPLE OF PROPORTIONALITY<br />

In this chapter, we discuss the function and scope of the principle of<br />

proportionality and similar balancing tests. We thereby understand proportionality<br />

not only as a judicial doctrine but also as legislative doctrine for the political<br />

institutions to follow. Proportionality is a trade-off-device which helps resolve<br />

conflicts between different norms, principles, and values. It is also a determining<br />

factor for the role of courts in reviewing administrative or legislative measures."<br />

Proportionality thus provides a legal standard against which individual or state<br />

measures can be reviewed." From a more procedural perspective, proportionality is<br />

closely related to the issues of intensity of review-the level of scrutiny exercised by<br />

judges-and whether there should be a full review on the merits or a more<br />

deferential standard of judicial review. 2<br />

A. Legal Principles<br />

We begin our discussion by providing some conceptual reflections about the<br />

nature of legal principles. This shall provide a basic framework for the subsequent<br />

analysis of the principle of proportionality in different legal fora. In this chapter, we<br />

primarily focus on the characteristics of, and the relationship between, legal rules<br />

and principles. This distinction features prominently in the writings of Ronald<br />

Dworkin and has subsequently been refined, most clearly by German constitutional<br />

scholars.<br />

There is no single authoritative definition of the concept of "legal principles,"<br />

either in domestic or in international law.' 3 The approach taken depends on a<br />

variety of factors, including the legal system at issue and the underlying legal<br />

10. Grinne de Bdrca, The Principle of Proportionality and its Application in EC <strong>Law</strong>, 13 Y.B. EUR.<br />

L. 105. 105 (1993).<br />

11. Malcolm Ross. Behind Proportionality: The Cultural and Constitutional Context, in ENGLISH<br />

PUBLIC LAW AND THE COMMON LAW OF EUROPE 83, 91 (Mads Andenas ed., 1998).<br />

12. NICHOLAS EMILIOU, THE PRINCIPLE OF PROPORTIONALITY IN EUROPEAN LAW: A<br />

COMPARATIVE STUDY 171-74 (1996).<br />

13. See Meinhard Hilf & Goetz Goettsche, The Relation of Economic and Non-Economic Principles<br />

in International <strong>Law</strong>, in INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC GOVERNANCE AND NON-ECONOMIC CONCERNS 5,<br />

9-10 (Stefan Griller ed., 2003) (defining "principles").<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 375 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

philosophy which informs the scholar's perspective on topics such as norms, rules,<br />

principles and values. Sometimes it also seems that continental lawyers are more<br />

interested in the search for underlying principles, taking the "top down" approach,<br />

as opposed to the common law "bottom up" approach.'<br />

The debate about, for instance, trade and environment or trade and human<br />

rights often reflects the crucial role that general principles may play in the WTO law.<br />

Economic and non-economic principles, from both within and outside the WTO<br />

legal order, often need to be reconciled with-and balanced against-each other. It<br />

has been argued that proportionality has to play a crucial role in guiding this<br />

'5<br />

process..<br />

Finally, it is evident that principles, as understood in legal theory, are not<br />

necessarily the same as principles (or general principles) of EC law, public<br />

international law, or WTO law. These general principles may also be rules in a<br />

theoretical sense (see the discussion below), depending on their normative content.<br />

Werner Schroeder has argued that basic principles of EC law sometimes have a very<br />

narrow focus and lay down clear normative consequences; as a result, their legal<br />

character is one of rules rather than of principles. 6<br />

1. Nature of Principles<br />

One recent suggestion to define principles is that they are "legal norms laying<br />

down essential elements of a legal order."' 7 Another formula is that principles<br />

"formulate general and flexible imperatives," which are "fundamental legal concepts<br />

and essential values of any legal system."' 8 Yet another suggestion is that a principle<br />

of law may be conceived as aiming at particularly valuable objectives and thereby<br />

"explains and justifies all or any of the more specific rules in question."' 9 While each<br />

of these definitions emphasizes a different aspect, taken together they provide a<br />

fuller picture of the basic nature of legal principles.<br />

Traditionally, legal norms have been divided into rules and principles. One<br />

may alternatively distinguish between rules and standards, 0 but our approach is to<br />

focus on the rules - principles dichotomy. 2 '<br />

14. Hilf, supra note 7, at 129. But see generally ALBERT DICEY, INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY OF<br />

THE LAW OF THE CONSTITUTION (10th ed. Macmillan 1960)(1885) (discussing the "guiding" or "leading"<br />

principles of the law of the constitution of England).<br />

15. Hilf & Goettsche, supra note 13, at 38.<br />

16. WERNER SCHROEDER, DAS GEMEINSCHAFTSRECHTSSYSTEM. EINE UNTERSUCHUNG ZU DEN<br />

RECHTSDOGMATISCHEN, RECHTSTHEORETISCHEN UND VERFASSUNGSRECHTLICHEN GRUNDLAGEN DES<br />

SYSTEMDENKENS IM EUROPAISCHEN GEMEINSCHAFTSRECHT [THE COMMUNITY LAW SYSTEM. A STUDY<br />

OF DOGMATIC, THEORETICAL, AND CONSTITUTIONAL LAW BASICS OF THE SYSTEMIC THINKING IN<br />

EUROPEAN COMMUNITY LAW] 266 (2002).<br />

17. Armin von Bogdandy, Doctrine of Principles 10 (N.Y.U. School of <strong>Law</strong> Jean Monnet Center,<br />

Working Paper 9/03, 2003), available at http://www.jeanmonnetprogram.org/papers/03/030901-01.pdf.<br />

18. Hilf & Goettsche, supra note 13, at 9-10.<br />

19. NEIL MACCORMICK, LEGAL REASONING AND LEGAL THEORY 152 (1978).<br />

20. There is also considerable discussion on this issue in the US legal literature which distinguishes<br />

between rules and standards. See Trachtman, supra note 1, at 45-46; Kathleen Sullivan, The Supreme<br />

Court, 1991 Term - Foreword: The Justices of Rules and Standards, 106 HARV. L. REV. 22, 58 (1992)<br />

(emphasizing that in Ronald Dworkin's theory of rules and principles, standards would be called<br />

principles).<br />

21. Ronald Dworkin famously distinguished between rules and principles, and many other legal<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 376 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

The main feature of rules is that they apply in an "all-or-nothing fashion." 22<br />

They may be either valid or invalid. 23 More technically speaking, the character of<br />

rules implies that they lay down a "binary validity claim." 24 Whenever there is a<br />

conflict of rules, this conflict can only be solved in two different ways: either by<br />

declaring one rule invalid or by "introducing an exception clause into one of the two<br />

rules., 2 1 In the second case, one of the rules is the exception to the other.<br />

Principles operate differently. They "express the idea of optimization." 26<br />

Principles are "norms commanding that something be realized to the highest degree<br />

that is actually and legally possible." 2 Accordingly, principles can be realized to<br />

different degrees, as opposed to the all-or-nothing approach underlying rules.<br />

Principles, similar to values, express the preference of some good over others.<br />

Whenever two countervailing principles collide, both will lay down competing<br />

optimization commands, and their relationship will not be absolute but relative. 6<br />

Principles are not invalidated (as this would be the case with rules); instead, they are<br />

outweighed, depending on each other's relative weight. It would not make sense to<br />

introduce an exception since one principle may not be the exception to another. 29<br />

Conflicts of principles can only be solved through a balancing act which takes<br />

into account each principle's weight. The "dimension of weight" is one of the main<br />

characteristics of principles." The weighing and balancing of countervailing<br />

principles will lead to a "conditional priority of one of the colliding principles over<br />

the other with respect to the circumstances of the case." 3 The assessment turns on<br />

the question of which principle carries relatively more weight. Note that the<br />

precedence of one principle over the other only relates to the specific facts of the<br />

case, and this relationship may change under different circumstances.<br />

In the context of international trade, this leads us to the preliminary conclusion<br />

that neither trade-related nor non-trade-related principles can be considered, from a<br />

legal point of view, as unconditionally preeminent. In many cases, their relationship<br />

can only be determined on the basis of the facts of an individual case.<br />

Principles play different functions in the legal order. One important aspect is<br />

that they fulfill an ordering function in a fragmented body of law and thus promote<br />

the coherence of the legal system. 2 Related is the function that principles help<br />

resolve ambiguities and fill gaps in the legal texts. Judicial reasoning and lawtheorists<br />

adopted this distinction as well. Despite some criticism raised against the rules - principles<br />

distinction, we believe it remains a useful and valuable conceptual tool to analyse legal norms and, in<br />

particular, to discuss the principle of proportionality and balancing. See RONALD DWORKIN, TAKING<br />

RIGHTS SERIOUSLY 24-26 (1978).<br />

22. Id. at 24.<br />

23. Id. (stating that "Jilf the facts a rule stipulates are given, then either the rule is valid, in which case<br />

the answer it supplies must be accepted, or it is not, in which case it contributes nothing to the decision.").<br />

24. JORGEN HABERMAS, BETWEEN FACTS AND NORMS: CONTRIBUTIONS TO A DISCOURSE THEORY<br />

OF LAW AND DEMOCRACY 255 (1996).<br />

25. Robert Alexy, On the Structure of Legal Principles, 13 RATIO JURIS 294, 295 (2000).<br />

26. Id. at 294.<br />

27. Id. at 295.<br />

28. Id. at 297.<br />

29. Id. at 296.<br />

30. DWORKIN, supra note 21, at 26.<br />

31. Alexy, supra note 25, at 296.<br />

32. von Bogdandy, supra note 17, at 7.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 377 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

making is supported by reference to general principles. Another crucial function of<br />

principles is that they can act as "'gateways' through which the legal order is<br />

attached to the broader public discourse."" All those aspects are relevant for WTO<br />

law as well, especially since it is in the process of evolving into a more mature legal<br />

system and generating some constitutional law-type norms, principles, and<br />

structures .<br />

Based on the preceding observations, one notes the crucial role that provisions<br />

such as Article XX GATT-and the legal rules and principles contained thereinplay<br />

in resolving conflicts between trade and non-trade interests." Framing those<br />

interests in terms of legally protected principles, trade-offs between principles are<br />

necessarily seen as relative, depending on the weighing and balancing of<br />

countervailing rights and interests in concrete circumstances. This weighing and<br />

balancing, undertaken by the judiciary, follows from the character of principles. An<br />

alternative approach could be to reduce the role of principles in the legal system by<br />

increasingly transforming them into specific legislative rules. This would reduce the<br />

discretion exercised by the judicial bodies and provide greater predictability. 36<br />

Conflicts between economic and non-economic values and interests can thus be<br />

resolved in different ways. First, it may be done through judicial balancing, based on<br />

legal provisions such as Article XX GATT or the relevant provisions in the SPS and<br />

TBT Agreements. Second, more specific legislation or treaty provisions may also<br />

address those concerns and reduce the discretion for the judicial bodies. 37 Given the<br />

frequent absence of specific rules on many sensitive issues and the prominent role of<br />

the dispute settlement process in shaping WTO law, the role and importance of<br />

principles has increased in the past and will continue to do so.<br />

Proportionality is commonly referred to as a legal principle. It can also be<br />

described as a test or standard, but its legal character is one of a principle. Robert<br />

Alexy wrote: "[t]he nature of principles implies the principle of proportionality and<br />

vice versa." 3 " The basic idea is that the principle of proportionality follows from the<br />

main characteristic of principles: the process of optimization.<br />

If one considers fundamental human rights as principles, one realizes how<br />

proportionality and its three-step analysis (suitability, necessity and proportionality<br />

stricto sensu) follows from the nature of competing principles: in the first step, the<br />

test of suitability is to avoid that measures, which are not capable at all of achieving<br />

the pursued objective, are adopted. Such measures do not bring any benefit to the<br />

objective pursued; and, instead, they only entail negative effects for other<br />

countervailing interests or principles. 3 9 The necessity element requires that the<br />

means employed to achieve the objective pursued by principle P 1 be the least<br />

intrusive with regard to countervailing principle P 2 . 40 Whenever there is a choice<br />

33. Id. at 8.<br />

34. See Deborah Cass, The "Constitutionalization" of International Trade <strong>Law</strong>: Judicial Norm-<br />

Generation as the Engine of Constitutional Development in International Trade, 12 EURO. J. INT'L L. 39, 42<br />

(2001).<br />

35. Joel Trachtman, The Domain of Dispute Resolution, 40 HARV. INT'L L. J. 333, 356 (1999).<br />

36. Id. at 350-54 (discussing rules and standards, the costs and benefits associated with them and their<br />

institutional and strategic dimensions).<br />

37. Id. at 376.<br />

38. ROBERT ALEXY, A THEORY OF CONSTITUTIONAL RIGHTS 66 (Julian Rivers trans., Oxford Univ.<br />

Press 2002) (1986).<br />

39. See id. at 68-69.<br />

40. "As a principle, P 2 requires optimizing relative to what is both legally and factually possible." Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 378 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

between different suitable measures, the least intrusive must be employed.<br />

Necessity therefore allows for a distinction and choice among different measures<br />

adopted on the basis of principle P,. But the broadest question of whether any<br />

measure should be chosen at all to pursue a certain objective is not part of the<br />

necessity analysis; this involves a true balancing of the competing principles P, and<br />

P. This final stage of the analysis, the process of weighing and balancing, is called<br />

proportionality in its narrow sense (proportionality stricto sensu). 4 1<br />

It is only in cases that have passed the necessity test that a balancing and<br />

weighing of competing principles will come into play. This final step, proportionality<br />

stricto sensu, is not guided by other substantive criteria, except for the criterion that<br />

the measures must not be excessive or disproportionate with regard to the pursued<br />

objective. One important requirement, however, is that the relative weight of each<br />

principle be taken into account."<br />

The remaining question is how the weighing in this process should be<br />

undertaken and whether there are any substantive criteria guiding the weighing. As<br />

stated, weighing is relative and depends on the circumstances of each individual case.<br />

It establishes a conditional, as opposed to an absolute, priority of colliding<br />

principles. 3 Weighing in that sense requires that the priority be established on the<br />

basis of reasons advanced in a discursive process.'<br />

This is the crucial link between the theory of principles and proportionality.<br />

The third step of the proportionality analysis may be regarded as a specific<br />

procedural obligation. It requires public authorities and the judiciary to justify their<br />

decisions on the basis of rational legal arguments and in a structured manner. 4 ' The<br />

factors that need to be considered and justified through legal reasoning are the<br />

weight attributed to each principle, the degree of interference with those principles,<br />

and the way in which those countervailing principles are balanced against each other.<br />

The importance of principles and proportionality increases in the absence of clear<br />

hierarchies of norms and whenever the outcome of a dispute cannot be determined<br />

simply on the basis of clear legislative provisions. A more principles-oriented<br />

approach (in conjunction with better rules) may help structure and rationalize the<br />

WTO legal system, clarify imprecise and open-ended provisions, and contribute to<br />

WTO law's growing maturity and sophistication in the years to come.<br />

2. Public International <strong>Law</strong> and WTO <strong>Law</strong><br />

In the previous section, we outlined some general features of legal principles.<br />

We now explore the role and legal status of general principles in public international<br />

law and in WTO law. General principles of international law have a very specific<br />

at 68.<br />

41. Id. at 67-68.<br />

42. See Alexy, supra note 26, at 298.<br />

43. MANFRED STELZER, DAS WESENSGEHALTSARGUMENT UND DER GRUNDSATZ DER<br />

VERHALTNISMA IGKEIT [ESSENTIAL CONTENT ARGUMENT AND THE PRINCIPLE OF PROPORTIONALITY]<br />

217-26 (1991).<br />

44. Id. at 223.<br />

45. Martin Borowski, Prinzipien als Grundrechtsnormen [Principles as Norms of Basic Rights], 53<br />

ZEITSCHRIFT FOR OFFENTLICHES RECHT [AUSTRIAN JOURNAL OF PUBLIC AND INTERNATIONAL LAW]<br />

307, 313-14 (1998).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 379 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

connotation, whereas our previous discussion of principles was more generic. In<br />

light of the overall topic of this paper, both aspects should be covered and brought<br />

together in an attempt to define the role and status of the principle of<br />

proportionality in the WTO legal order.<br />

General principles are a well-known and yet somewhat vague concept in public<br />

international law. 46 Article 38(1)(c) of the Statute of the International Court of<br />

Justice (ICJ) lists "general principles of law" as one of the sources of international<br />

law. In international law, principles play an important role in filling the gaps left by<br />

the international legal order and to avoid a non liquet in rulings by international<br />

judges. 4 ' Furthermore, they are crucial for international tribunals which may refer to<br />

general principles to justify their own decisions, because they provide a conceptual<br />

background for the interpretation of the law and state practice. 49 The openness of<br />

principles to public and legal discourse is reflected in the fact that they help the<br />

judiciary construe the law "in a dynamic fashion responsive to today's problems." 5<br />

In cases of conflict between general principles and other specific norms of<br />

international law (treaties or customs), the norms will generally prevail." In the<br />

context of WTO law, "a principle could not be used with the effect of overriding a<br />

specific rule contained in the WTO agreements. 5 2 General principles only have a<br />

subsidiary function in the international legal order.<br />

General principles may originate from different sources. Some principles may<br />

be derived from domestic law, from which they are borrowed and distilled on a<br />

comparative basis. 3 On the other hand, general principles of international law are<br />

unique to international law, even though they mostly overlap with the general<br />

principles of law recognized by Article 38 of the Statute of the ICJ. One standard<br />

textbook definition of general principles of international law is that they are<br />

"primarily abstractions from a mass of rules and have been so long and so generally<br />

accepted as to be no longer directly connected with state practice.""<br />

Examples of general principles, which may be either procedural or substantive<br />

in nature, are the following: pacta sunt servanda, principles governing the judicial<br />

process, res judicata, and the principles of equity, good faith, equality of states,<br />

interpretation, right to self-defense, and right to independence. 5 It has been argued<br />

that proportionality is also characterized as a general principle of international law,<br />

with its own foundations in the international legal order. 56<br />

46. In EC law, general principles provide guidance for the interpretation of primary and secondary<br />

Community law and the exercise of powers by the institutions, and determine the legality of acts of the<br />

Community institutions and the member states, and, finally, fill gaps where lacunae exist in Community<br />

law. With regard to the principle of proportionality, see EMILIOU, supra note 12, at 121.<br />

47. Statute of the International Court of Justice art. 38(1)(c).<br />

48. JOOST PAUWELYN, CONFLICT OF NORMS IN PUBLIC INTERNATIONAL LAW: How WTO LAW<br />

RELATES TO OTHER RULES OF INTERNATIONAL LAW 129 (2003).<br />

49. PIERRE-MARIE Dupuy, DROIT INTERNATIONAL PUBLIC 303 (4th ed. 1998).<br />

50. PAUWELYN, supra note 48, at 130.<br />

51. Principles that are jus cogens are an exception.. See Hilf, supra note 11, at 128.<br />

52. Id.<br />

53. IAN BROWNLIE, PRINCIPLES OF PUBLIC INTERNATIONAL LAW 16-18 (6th ed. 2003).<br />

54. Id. at 18-19 (emphasis omitted).<br />

55. PAUWELYN, supra note 48, at 125-126.<br />

56. Riccardo Mazzeschi, Book Review, 13 EURO. J. INT'L L. 1031, 1035 (2002) (reviewing ENZO<br />

CANNIZZARO, IL PRINCIPIO DELLA PROPORZIONALITA NELL'ORDINAMENTO INTERNAZIONALE [THE<br />

PRINCIPLE OF PROPORTIONALITY IN INTERNATIONAL LAW] (2000)).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 380 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

WTO law is a branch of international law, and the WTO agreements need to be<br />

interpreted against the background of general principles of public international law. 57<br />

The preamble to the Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization (WTO<br />

Agreement) states that the parties to the WTO Agreement are "determined to<br />

preserve the basic principles and to further the objectives underlying this multilateral<br />

trading system. ''8 As Meinhard Hilf pointed out, there is no list of principles which<br />

one could refer to, and it is unclear whether those principles only encompass the<br />

economic justifications and objectives of the WTO system.S 9 The long list of basic<br />

principles suggested by Hilf and Goettsche includes trade liberalization, sovereignty<br />

and national deference, sustainable development, non-discrimination, transparency,<br />

rule of law, due process, good faith, natural justice, and proportionality.' Cameron<br />

and Gray point to similar principles, such as the principles of effectiveness in treaty<br />

interpretation, in dubio mitius, legitimate expectations, non-retroactivity of treaties,<br />

state responsibility, estoppel, abuse of rights, and exhaustion of local remedies. 6<br />

Proportionality has not explicitly been recognized as a general principle of WTO<br />

law, even though it has been referred to by the appellate body to interpret individual<br />

provisions of the WTO Agreements. 6 The point of reference has been the principle<br />

of proportionality as applied in the law on international countermeasures. In Cotton<br />

Yarn, the appellate body concluded:<br />

It would be absurd if the breach of an international obligation were<br />

sanctioned by proportionate countermeasures, while, in the absence of<br />

such breach, a WTO Member would be subject to a disproportionate and,<br />

hence, "punitive", attribution of serious damage not wholly caused by its<br />

exports. In our view, such an exorbitant derogation from the principle of<br />

proportionality . .. could be justified only if the drafters of the ATC<br />

[Agreement on Textiles and Clothing] had expressly provided for it, which<br />

is not the case. 63<br />

3. Conclusions<br />

Many conflicts between legal provisions are not only conflicts of rules but also<br />

conflicts of principles. From a theoretical perspective, those conflicts may thus<br />

consist of conflicts between rules, principles, as well as rules and principles.<br />

57. JOHN JACKSON, THE WORLD TRADING SYSTEM 120 (2d ed. 1997): see generally PAUWELYN,<br />

supra note 48, ch. 2.<br />

58. Preamble to the Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization (WTO Agreement)<br />

Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, Legal Instruments-Results of the<br />

Uruguay Round, 33 I.L.M. 1125 (1994).<br />

59. Hilf, supra note 7, at 112.<br />

60. Hilf & Goettsche, supra note 13, at 16-17.<br />

61. See generally James Cameron & Kevin Gray, Principles of International <strong>Law</strong> in the WTO Dispute<br />

Settlement Body, 50 INT'L & COMP. L. Q. 248. 256. 258, 260, 270, 292-95 (2001).<br />

62. Appellate Body Report, United <strong>State</strong>s - Definitive Safeguard Measures on Imports of Circular<br />

Welded Carbon Quality Line Pipe from Korea, paras. 256-260, WT/DS202/AB/R (Feb. 15, 2002)<br />

[hereinafter US - Line Pipe], available at http://www.wto.org/english/tratop-e/dispu-e/202abr-e.pdf.<br />

63. Appellate Body Report, United <strong>State</strong>s - Transitional Safeguard Measure on Combed Cotton Yarn<br />

from Pakistan, para. 120, WT/DS192/AB/R (Oct. 8, 2001) [hereinafter US - Cotton Yarn], available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/english/tratop-e/dispu-e/192abr-e.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 381 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

We shall make one caveat. "Global" principles of administrative law need to be<br />

reflected carefully, especially when transplanting national or European<br />

constitutional concepts to the WTO level." Analogies and transfers must, in each<br />

case, reflect the specific legal and political system in which they operate, in particular<br />

since legal principles from a variety of national legal orders seem to resemble each<br />

other. <strong>Law</strong>yers from different backgrounds may approach the same principles with<br />

different concepts in mind and may speak about the same legal phenomenon using<br />

different terminology: "[a]pparently identical words may have a different meaning<br />

and apparently different words may have the same meaning." 65 ' In any case, one<br />

must not disregard the different forms of national constitutional and international<br />

law traditions which shape the thinking about principles-what they are as well as<br />

what they are based upon. In the European context, Jtirgen Habermas rightly<br />

warned that:<br />

the same legal principles would also have to be interpreted from the<br />

perspectives of different national traditions and histories. One's own<br />

tradition must in each case be appropriated from a vantage point<br />

relativized by the perspectives of other traditions, and appropriated in<br />

such a manner that it can be brought into a transnational, Western<br />

European constitutional culture.'<br />

The concepts of proportionality, necessity, balancing, and reasonableness are<br />

widely used in many different jurisdictions. As we attempt to show throughout this<br />

article, their use and connotation varies from author to author, and from jurisdiction<br />

to jurisdiction. It is often difficult to reflect on one particular concept since it may be<br />

understood in many different ways. Proportionality, for instance, may generally be<br />

understood as a very strict test of review or a more relaxed and deferential test of<br />

review. Our own approach is influenced by the classical three-step proportionality<br />

test, developed in continental European legal thinking.<br />

B. Introducing Proportionality<br />

The principle of proportionality has many different facets. It is regularly<br />

invoked but its function, constituent elements, and scope of application often remain<br />

elusive. Proportionality is not a standardized legal concept and to a large extent<br />

depends on the legal regime within which it is used. The simplest formula to explain<br />

proportionality is the prohibition on using a "steam hammer to crack a nut, if a<br />

nutcracker would do., 67 This formula is quite illustrative but not very helpful in<br />

addressing complex legal question that arise in connection with the proportionality<br />

test.<br />

Characterizing proportionality at a very general level, one of its key functions is<br />

to define the relationship between the state and its citizens, resolving conflicts of<br />

64. Giacinto Della Cananea, Beyond the <strong>State</strong>: the Europeanization and Globalization of Procedural<br />

Administrative <strong>Law</strong>, 9 EURO. PUB. L. 563, 563 (2003); John M. Jackson, Fragmentation or Unification<br />

Among International Institutions: The World Trade Organization, 31 N.Y.U. J. INT'L L. & POL. 823, 829<br />

(1999).<br />

65. Van Hoecke, supra note 9, at 10-11.<br />

66. HABERMAS, supra note 24, at 500.<br />

67. R v. Goldstein (1983) 1 W.L.R. 151,155 (UKHL)(Eng.).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 382 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

interest between these two spheres. More specifically, proportionality in its<br />

traditional form has provided a tool to define and restrain the regulatory freedom of<br />

governments. Proportionality "sets material limits to the interference of public<br />

authorities into the private sphere of the citizen . . .<br />

Proportionality as a legal concept mainly developed in the context of German<br />

Police <strong>Law</strong> (Polizeirecht) about a century ago.' The principle related to the<br />

interference by administrative authorities with civil liberties. 70 The German courts<br />

used proportionality to assess whether the measures taken by the police were more<br />

intrusive than necessary to achieve a certain objective. 7 ' In German administrative<br />

law, proportionality developed as a device to control the discretion exercised by the<br />

administration. 72 Some decades later, the principle of proportionality was also<br />

introduced to impose limitations upon the discretion of the legislator to enact<br />

legislation. This can be considered as the constitutional law aspect of proportionality<br />

as it is well-known it in many (federal) legal systems.<br />

The previous paragraph identified the two different ways in which the principle<br />

of proportionality can be applied. First, as a legislative and administrative doctrine<br />

which guides the actions of the legislator and the administration by establishing a<br />

standard against which those actions are measured. Second, as a judicial doctrine<br />

which lays down a specific standard of review applied by the judiciary in reviewing<br />

legislative and administrative measures. The proportionality test requires an active<br />

role to be performed by the judiciary."<br />

C. Test in Different Contexts<br />

Proportionality has developed as a test of review. It is used in different<br />

contexts. First, it is recognized in some systems as the test for the exercise of<br />

competences. Secondly, it is used to review justifications for interference with or<br />

restrictions on rights. Thirdly, it is also used to determine the extension of rights.<br />

Other limiting mechanisms, such as leaving national authorities a "margin of<br />

appreciation" in European Convention on Human Rights (ECHR) law, or having a<br />

rule of reason in U.S. federal anti trust law, may in fact incorporate similar balancing<br />

exercises.<br />

In ECHR law, for instance, proportionality is applied in at least three different<br />

contexts: first, as a benchmark to establish the legality of derogations; second, with<br />

the aim to establish the legality of interferences by states with Convention rights;<br />

and, third, to determine scope of application of some of the rights established by the<br />

Convention.<br />

On a more general level, a first use of proportionality is as a general test for the<br />

exercise of competences. This aspect features in domestic legal systems (e.g. control<br />

68. Jiurgen Schwarze, The Principle of Proportionality and the Principle of Impartiality in European<br />

Administrative <strong>Law</strong>, 1 RIVISTA TRIMESTRALE DI DIRITTO PUBBLICO [QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF PUBLIC<br />

LAW] 53, 53 (2003).<br />

69. Id. at 55.<br />

70. Id.<br />

71. Id.<br />

72. EKKEHART STEIN & GOTZ FRANK. STAATSRECHT 240 (19th ed. 2004).<br />

73. de Btirca, supra note 10, at 105.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 383 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

of discretion in German administrative law), 74 as well as EU law. In the latter case,<br />

the Community courts control the exercise of discretion conferred on the<br />

Community institutions and, in particular, the European Commission. There are<br />

differences in the intensity of review depending on the area and subject matter of the<br />

decision. A second use relates to justifications for interference with, or restrictions<br />

on, rights. This is typically the case in areas such as EC free movement law, national<br />

constitutional law, the law of the ECHR and human rights in English law. In<br />

addition to the differences in the intensity of review depending on the area and<br />

subject matter of the decision, the kinds of rights involved provide another variable.<br />

D. Typology of Functions<br />

In this section, we distill the main functions of the principle of proportionality,<br />

many of which are also reflected in the debate on judicial review in the WTO and the<br />

balancing of trade and non-trade interests. Each of the functions mentioned below<br />

emphasizes one particular aspect of the principle of proportionality, so they should<br />

be regarded as complementary to each other.<br />

1. Control and Limitation of Discretion<br />

The basic idea underlying proportionality is that citizens of liberal states should<br />

only have their freedom of action limited insofar as is necessary for the public<br />

interest. Public authorities should, in the choice of their measures, choose the least<br />

onerous one. The principle of proportionality guides this process and thereby<br />

imposes restrictions on the regulatory freedom of governments.<br />

The proportionality test, as a key legal instrument to control and check the<br />

discretion exercised by the administration, involves a means-ends relationship. 75 It<br />

establishes both a guideline as to the use of discretion by national authorities and a<br />

standard against which decisions are measured. The means employed by public<br />

authorities to attain a legitimate objective have to be the least onerous choice, and<br />

the impact on individual rights must not be out of proportion to the aim pursued.<br />

Democratic control over state actions is guaranteed through the close relationship<br />

between the rule of law and the principle of proportionality, whereby<br />

proportionality links the behaviour of public authorities to the rule of law. Modern<br />

thinking about the role of proportionality in public administration emphasizes that<br />

proportionality requires the administration to balance all relevant interests at issue<br />

and then to use its discretionary powers in light of this balancing exercise. 76<br />

74. Different conceptual approaches towards administrative law exist in the European legal systems.<br />

Traditionally, the French system emphasized the discretion or freedom of the administration to take<br />

decisions, whereas the German system focused on the protection of individual rights of citizens. Changes<br />

and convergences have occurred in the recent past. Jiirgen Schwarze, Konvergenz im Verwaltungsrecht der<br />

EU-Mitgliedstaaten [Convergence of Administrative <strong>Law</strong> of the EU Member-<strong>State</strong>s], DEUTSCHES<br />

VERWALTUNGSBLAT-r [GERMAN ADMINISTRATION JOURNAL] 881-89 (1996).<br />

75. EMILIOU, supra note 12, at 23-24.<br />

76. Theo Ohlinger, Die Verwaltung zwischen Gesetz, Billigkeit und Biirgerniihe [Administration<br />

between <strong>Law</strong>, Fairness and Closeness to the People], ZEITSCHRIFT FOR VERWALTUNG [AUSTRIAN<br />

ADMINISTRATION JOURNAL] 678 (1999).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 384 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

2. Balancing of Conflicting Rights and Interests<br />

Whenever there is a conflict of rights, values and interests, this conflict will<br />

often need to be resolved through a judicial balancing act. If this process is guided<br />

by the principle of proportionality, the conflicting objectives will be reconciled<br />

through the application of the three-step proportionality test.<br />

Proportionality is applied, amongst others, to review domestic measures<br />

restricting the free movement within the EC Internal Market. In this context,<br />

proportionality guides the balancing process between free trade objectives and other<br />

legitimate public policy objectives. This reasoning also generally applies to WTO<br />

law, even though proportionality and balancing are not used as openly as in EC<br />

law. 77 The balancing aspect is also part of the proportionality and necessity tests in<br />

public international law.<br />

Frequently, competing interests and values are framed in terms of clear and<br />

precise rules elaborated by the law and policymaking process. If that is not the case,<br />

balancing of competing interests and values needs to be undertaken in the judicial<br />

arena and judges are required to make the necessary trade-offs according to the<br />

weight attributed to the different rights, interest, and values. It can be argued that<br />

the growing demand for necessity testing and balancing in WTO dispute settlement<br />

reflects the inability of the WTO's bodies to "legislate" on many of the complex<br />

issues." The danger is that judges then act as substitute legislators.<br />

The purpose of proportionality in such circumstances is to provide a test against<br />

which the balancing of conflicting interests may take place in a structured and<br />

deliberate manner. Legally, proportionality governs the ad hoc and variable<br />

substantive relationship between rules and principles and provides a rational legal<br />

tool to make the necessary trade-offs.<br />

3. Standard for Judicial Review<br />

Proportionality as a general principle of law underlies legislative and<br />

administrative actions. At the same time it is also used as a standard for judicial<br />

review.<br />

The proportionality test is usually associated with a full review on the merits,<br />

going beyond the more traditional and narrower concept of a reasonableness review<br />

of the initial decision.9 Judges applying the principle of proportionality also define a<br />

particularly active role for the judiciary within the legal system: the review of<br />

administrative or legislative measures on the merits. The fact that courts apply the<br />

proportionality test as an independent ground of review has always raised concerns<br />

77. Desmedt. supra note 4, at 445.<br />

78. Trachtman, supra note 1, at 85.<br />

79. Under the traditional Wednesbury test in English law a decision can be challenged "if it is so<br />

unreasonable that no reasonable public body could have made it." PAUL P. CRAIG. ADMINISTRATIVE<br />

LAW 537 (4th ed., 1999); see also R (Daly) v. Secretary of <strong>State</strong> for the Home Department [2001] UKHL 26,<br />

[2001] 2 A.C. 532, and Huang v Secretary of <strong>State</strong> for the Home Department, [2007] UKHL 11.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 385 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

about undue judicial interference with administrative and legislative decisionmaking,<br />

the separation of powers, and balancing undertaken by the judiciary."<br />

We can illustrate this point by reference to English law. Traditionally, the<br />

discretion exercised by public authorities was reviewed by the courts, which applied<br />

a deferential reasonableness test, the so-called Wednesbury test." Justification for<br />

this test was based on the constitutional position of the courts. The intensity with<br />

which courts apply the reasonableness test also depends on the subject matter at<br />

issue, ranging from fundamental rights to economic policy choices. Paul Craig has<br />

argued that in the context of English law, a proportionality test would provide a<br />

more structured formula than the Wednesbury test, because it would require both<br />

the administration and the courts to justify their decisions." Another argument in<br />

favor of the adoption of the proportionality test is that it demands a more reasoned<br />

analysis from the decision-maker than the imprecise reasonableness test. 83 Possible<br />

arguments against the adoption of the proportionality test as an independent ground<br />

of review relate to the separation of powers, the lack of expertise of the courts in the<br />

relevant area, and the fact that certain issues may be unsuited to a proportionality<br />

analysis." Recently, due to the adoption of the Human Rights Act 1998, the<br />

proportionality test, rather than the more deferential Wednesbury test, has become a<br />

key feature of judicial review in English law.<br />

4. Scope of Legal Norms<br />

Proportionality is also a tool to determine the scope and limitations of legal<br />

norms. Examples include the inherent limitations of the free movement provisions,<br />

such as the rule of reason in the context of Article 28 of the EC Treaty (the judicially<br />

created "mandatory requirements" doctrine). 8 5 Other examples include the<br />

provisions on unlawful discrimination in ECHR and EC law. Despite the usually<br />

general wording of equality provisions, differences in treatment are allowed under<br />

certain circumstances. Proportionality serves the purpose to determine whether<br />

discrimination can be objectively and reasonably justified and thus does not fall afoul<br />

of the equality principle. The non-discrimination provisions include a kind of rule of<br />

reason.<br />

5. Limit and Rationalize the Power of Judges<br />

The proportionality test and its three-step structure also provides an important<br />

tool to confine the legal authority conferred on judges. As stated above, one<br />

important aspect of the principle of proportionality is that it is a key tool for the<br />

80. See Paul Craig, Theory and Values in Public <strong>Law</strong>: A Response, in LAW AND ADMINISTRATION IN<br />

EUROPE: ESSAYS IN HONOUR OF CAROL HARLOW 38 (Paul Craig & Richard Rawlings eds., 2003).<br />

81. Associated Provincial Picture Houses v. Wednesbury Corp., (1948) 1 K.B. 223, 230 (Eng.).<br />

82. Paul Craig, Unreasonableness and Proportionality in UK <strong>Law</strong>, in THE PRINCIPLE OF<br />

PROPORTIONALITY IN THE LAWS OF EUROPE 99 (Evelyn Ellis, ed., 1999).<br />

83. Id. at 100.<br />

84. Id. at 102-03.<br />

85. See Treaty Establishing the European Community, Dec. 24, 2002, 2002 O.J. (C 325/33) art. 28<br />

[hereinafter EC Treaty]; see also Case 120/78 Rewe-Zentral AG v. Bundesmonopolverwaltung far<br />

Branntwein (Cassis de Dijon) [1979] ECR 649. The rule of reason has also been applied in the EU<br />

competition law field in interpreting arts. 81 and 82.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 386 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

judiciary to give substance to relatively open-ended norms by connecting them to<br />

their objectives. Counterbalancing such far-reaching powers wielded by the<br />

judiciary, proportionality introduces rational legal arguments in the decision-making<br />

process. Those arguments need to be presented and justified by the parties to a<br />

dispute and the judiciary in a public, deliberative process. The requirement ensures<br />

that through the three-step analysis, the interests at stake, the weight attributed to<br />

conflicting norms, and the other reasoning applied are made transparent.'<br />

6. Political Theory and Proportionality<br />

Finally, proportionality can be approached from the angle of different political<br />

theory. Pluralists may look at proportionality as a tool to enhance participation<br />

rights by requiring authorities to consider carefully the views of interested parties. 8<br />

Liberals may be particularly interested in the three-step structure of the<br />

proportionality analysis which requires the administration to justify its decisions<br />

along the lines of the different steps." 0 Proportionality thus becomes a tool to<br />

enhance accountability and justification for governmental action. 89 Additionally,<br />

judges may also become more accountable since they also have to justify their<br />

decisions in a detailed fashion. Finally, republicans may consider proportionality as<br />

"a defence against naked political bargain" because it prevents some influential<br />

groups from getting exclusive access to the decision-making process.9<br />

86. See Craig, supra note 82, at 99-100. In the case of R (Daly) v. Secretary of <strong>State</strong> for the Home<br />

Department, he pointed out that neither the traditional approach to judicial review in English law as<br />

formulated in Associated Provincial Picture Houses Ltd v. Wednesbury Corporation nor the heightened<br />

scrutiny approach adopted in R v. Ministry of Defence, Ex. P. Smith had provided adequate protection of<br />

European Convention rights as required under the Human Rights Act 1998, as held by the European<br />

Court of Human Rights (the 'Strasbourg court') in Smith and Grady v. United Kingdom. R (Daly) v.<br />

Secretary of <strong>State</strong> for the Home Department [2001] UKHL 26, [2001] 2 A.C. 532, paras 26-28. Having<br />

referred to a material difference between the Wednesbury and Smith approach on the one hand and the<br />

proportionality approach applicable where European Convention rights are at stake on the other, he said:<br />

"This does not mean that there has been a shift to merits review." Id. para. 28. In the case of Huang v.<br />

Secretary of <strong>State</strong> for the Home Department, the House of Lords revisited Daly and Lord Steyn's statement:<br />

This statement has, it seems, given rise to some misunderstanding. . . The point which, as we<br />

understand, Lord Steyn wished to make was that, although the Convention calls for a more exacting<br />

standard of review, it remains the case that the judge is not the primary decision-maker. It is not for<br />

him to decide what the recruitment policy for the armed forces should be. In proceedings under the<br />

Human Rights Act, of course, the court would have to scrutinise the policy and any justification<br />

advanced for it to see whether there was sufficient justification for the discriminatory treatment.<br />

Huang v Secretary of <strong>State</strong> for the Home Department, [2007] UKHL 11 para. 13. The transparency and<br />

predictability achieved in tying the review to a three-step approach has not been accorded judicial<br />

attention in this way by English courts: the proportionality test has been regarded as determined by<br />

European Human Rights law or European Union <strong>Law</strong>.<br />

87. Craig, supra note 80, at 38-39. Note that Craig's arguments are situated within the context of<br />

judicial review of agency decisions in the UK.<br />

88. Id. at 38.<br />

89. Id.<br />

90. Id. at 39.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 387 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

E. Different Elements of the Proportionality Test<br />

The principle of proportionality, in its most elaborate form, consists of three<br />

different elements: suitability, necessity, and proportionality stricto sensu<br />

(proportionality in the narrow sense). 9 ' These elements need to be assessed<br />

cumulatively, but they are in ascending order in terms of intensity with which the<br />

measure is reviewed. 9<br />

There is no single coherent principle of proportionality. Its constituent<br />

elements vary, as well as the degree and intensity of review imposed. It can also be<br />

the case that similar tests are given different names, such as necessity,<br />

reasonableness, 9 cost-benefit-analysis, 94 or rationality review, and yet their<br />

normative requirements may be very similar to the proportionality test.<br />

1. Suitability<br />

Suitability is the first step of assessment. It requires that the adopted measure<br />

is suitable or appropriate to achieve the objective it pursues. 95 In other words,<br />

suitability requires "a causal relationship between the the measure and its object. 9 6<br />

It can easily be argued that measures which are not suitable at all to pursue the<br />

stated objective should not be imposed on that basis. 97 Another function of this stage<br />

of assessment is to single out measures that claim to protect the general interest<br />

while, in reality, they have a protectionist purpose.<br />

Courts have to determine the moment at which the suitability of a measure, as<br />

an objective standard should be assessed. In a given case, it may make a difference<br />

whether the measure is evaluated from an ex ante perspective (the moment when the<br />

91. Jan H. Jans, Proportionality Revisited, 27 LEGAL ISSUES OF ECON. INTEGRATION 239, 240-41<br />

(2000).<br />

92. Id. The order of the steps and their emphasis may differ. For instance, in de Freitas v Permanent<br />

Secretary of Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries, Lands and Housing [1999] 1 A.C. 69, at 80, the Privy<br />

Council, drawing on South African, Canadian and Zimbabwean authority, defined the questions generally<br />

to be asked in deciding whether a measure is proportionate: "whether: (i) the legislative objective is<br />

sufficiently important to justify limiting a fundamental right; (ii) the measures designed to meet the<br />

legislative objective are rationally connected to it; and (iii) the means used to impair the right or freedom<br />

are no more than is necessary to accomplish the objective." See also Aharon Barak, The Proportional<br />

Effect: The Israeli Experience, 57 U. Toronto L.J. 369 (2007) and Dieter Grimm, Proportionality in<br />

Canadian and German Constitutional Jurisprudence, 57 U. Toronto L.J. 383 (2007) (providing further<br />

comparative analysis, on the steps of the proportionality analysis and the relative role of the different steps<br />

by two senior judges and academic scholars).<br />

93. For the use of the concept of reasonableness in the sense of proportionality, see Federico Ortino,<br />

From "Non-discrimination" to "Reasonableness": A Paradigm Shift for International Economic <strong>Law</strong>? 33-37<br />

(N.Y.U. School of <strong>Law</strong> Jean Monnet Center, Working Paper 01105, 2005), available at<br />

http://www.jeanmonnetprogram.org/papers/05/050101.pdf (distinguishing between substantive and<br />

procedural reasonableness).<br />

94. See Trachtman, supra note 1, at 80-82 (pointing out the similarities and differences between<br />

proportionality, balancing and cost-benefit-analysis).<br />

95. JUKK.k SNELL, GOODS AND SERVICES IN EC LAW: A STUDY OF THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN<br />

THE FREEDOMS 196 (2002).<br />

96. Jans, supra note 91, at 240..<br />

97. See Joined Cases 62 & 63/81 Seco v. ttablissement d'Assurance, 1982 E.C.R. 223, 236-37; Case C-<br />

240/95, Criminal proceedings against R~my Schmit, 1996 E.C.R. 1-3179, 1-3200. In German law, see<br />

BVerwGE 27, 181,187-88 (parking prohibition).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 388 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

measure was enacted) or an ex post perspective (the moment when the measure is<br />

analyzed by the court). In domestic law, the legislator is often granted a certain<br />

"right to err" in making his appraisals about future developments, operation, and<br />

effectiveness of the measure adopted. Thus, the scope of discretion granted to the<br />

initial decision maker will also affect the intensity of review-ranging from mere<br />

review of evidence to intense substantive review of the decision.<br />

2. Necessity<br />

The necessity test requires that the objective, upon which a measure is based,<br />

cannot be achieved by alternative means that are less restrictive than the measure<br />

adopted. If there is a choice between several appropriate measures, the least<br />

onerous and equally effective measure needs to be selected. 9 " This is often called the<br />

"least restrictive alternative." 99 The test combines two questions. The first question<br />

is whether there are less restrictive, or milder, measures. Secondly, one needs to ask<br />

whether the alternative measures are equally effective in achieving the pursued<br />

objective." °<br />

The underlying objective of this test is that the measure adopted by the state<br />

should do minimal harm to citizens or the public interest. In the trade context, the<br />

necessity requires the states to impose the least trade-restrictive measure in pursuing<br />

non-trade-related domestic policy objectives.<br />

Referring to an example from the case law of the ECJ, the Court in de Peijper<br />

ruled out the necessity of domestic legislation which the Dutch authorities tried to<br />

justify on public health grounds. The ECJ held that the measure was not necessary<br />

since the domestic authorities could have pursued the same objective as effectively<br />

by adopting other means which were less-restrictive to intra-Community trade.'<br />

'<br />

In<br />

Familiapress, another free movement case, the ECJ ruled that it was for the national<br />

court to assess whether the national prohibition was "proportionate to the aim of<br />

maintaining press diversity and whether that objective might not be attained by<br />

measures less restrictive of both intra-Community trade and freedom of<br />

expression. ' '<br />

In some English cases, such as the Shayler judgment, necessity is obviously<br />

interpreted differently than the classical three-step test outlined in this chapter.' 3<br />

98. SNELL, supra note 95, at 198.<br />

99. Jans, supra note 91, at 240.<br />

100. FEDERICO ORTINO, BASIC LEGAL INSTRUMENTS FOR THE LIBERALISATION OF TRADE: A<br />

COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF EC AND WTO LAW 471 (2004).<br />

101. Case 104/75, Adriaan de Peijper, 1976 E.C.R. 613, 636.<br />

102. Case C-368/95, Familiapress v. Bauer Verlag, 1997 E.C.R. 1-3689, 1-3717. See also Case C-275/92,<br />

Her Majesty's Customs & Excise v. Schindler, 1994 E.C.R. 1-1039 (granting the domestic authorities a wide<br />

margin of discretion to restrict or prohibit certain types of lotteries on public policy grounds).<br />

103. R. v. Shayler, (2003) 1 A.C. 247 (UKHL)(Eng.)(relating to the compatibility of Official Secrets<br />

Act 1989 with the Human Rights Act 1998). See R (Daly) v. Secretary of <strong>State</strong> for the Home Department<br />

[2001] UKHL 26, [2001] 2 A.C. 532; Huang v. Secretary of <strong>State</strong> for the Home Department, [2007] UKHL<br />

11; but see de Freitas v. Permanent Secretary of Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries, Lands and Housing<br />

[1999] 1 A.C. 69 (laying down another version of the three step test which has been followed in the<br />

subsequent case law).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 389 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

The English courts in these cases have tended to align "necessity" with the principle<br />

of proportionality stricto sensu. The relevant part of Shayler reads as follows:<br />

It is plain from the language of article 10(2), and the European Court [of<br />

Human Rights] has repeatedly held, that any national restriction on<br />

freedom of expression can be consistent with article 10(2) only if it is<br />

prescribed by law, is directed to one or more of the objectives specified in<br />

the article and is shown by the state concerned to be necessary in a<br />

democratic society. "Necessary" has been strongly interpreted: it is not<br />

synonymous with "indispensable", neither has it the flexibility of such<br />

expressions as "admissible", "ordinary", "useful", "reasonable" or<br />

"desirable".. . . One must consider whether the interference complained<br />

of corresponded to a pressing social need, whether it was proportionate to<br />

the legitimate aim pursued and whether the reasons given by the national<br />

authority to justify it are relevant and sufficient under article 10(2) .... ."<br />

This quote illustrates quite well that necessity concepts may differ and yet<br />

reflect the same underlying concerns.<br />

3. Proportionality Stricto Sensu<br />

The third step is to analyze whether the effects of a measure are<br />

disproportionate or excessive in relation to the interests affected. This final stage of<br />

assessment comes into play once a measure has been found suitable and necessary to<br />

achieve a particular objective. It is at this stage that a true weighing and balancing of<br />

competing objectives takes place. The more intense the restriction of a particular<br />

interest, the more important the justification for the countervailing objective needs<br />

to be.' 5<br />

This third step will often not be reached. In EC law, the necessity analysis<br />

dominates most cases where the ECJ has applied the proportionality test. In some<br />

other cases, the ECJ tended to disguise proportionality stricto sensu as a normal<br />

necessity analysis, and it did not explicitly address the third step of analysis.' °6<br />

Within the necessity test, the Court has conducted a marginal review of<br />

proportionality, as some cases on consumer protection and product labeling<br />

illustrate.' 7 The Court has hereby implicitly questioned the level of protection<br />

adopted by the Member <strong>State</strong>s, in addition to a traditional review of suitability and<br />

necessity of the domestic measures.<br />

In those rather rare cases where the ECJ has applied proportionality stricto<br />

sensu, it has usually reviewed the objectives submitted by the Member <strong>State</strong>s to<br />

justify their domestic measures. In Stoke-on-Trent, the Court outlined<br />

proportionality stricto sensu in the most unambiguous way:<br />

104. Id. at 268-69.<br />

105. STEIN & FRANK, supra note 72, at 243.<br />

106. ORTINO, supra note 100, at 471.<br />

107. See Case 120/78, Rewe-Zentral v. Bundesmonopolverwaltung fur Branntwein, 1979 E.C.R. 649<br />

(holding that the fixing of a minimum alcohol content for alcoholic beverages is prohibited by Article 30 of<br />

the EEC Treaty) [hereinafter Cassis de Dijon]; see also Case 178/84, Comm'n v. Germany, 1987 E.C.R.<br />

1227 [hereinafter German Beer].<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 390 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

Appraising the proportionality of national rules which pursue a legitimate<br />

aim under Community law involves weighing the national interest in<br />

attaining that aim against the Community interest in ensuring the free<br />

movement of goods.'a'<br />

It should be noted that this was a rather exceptional statement in the<br />

jurisprudence of the ECJ.'" Nevertheless, this statement highlights that balancing in<br />

the trade context usually involves the comparison of the value and the importance of<br />

the national objective upon which the measure is based with the overall interest in<br />

ensuring free trade. The relative costs and benefits of the domestic measure and the<br />

restrictions imposed on free trade will be assessed.<br />

Danish Bottles is a classic case in which the ECJ applied the full proportionality<br />

test in the area of domestic environmental protection. It found that:<br />

[T]he system for returning non-approved containers is capable of<br />

protecting the environment and . . . affects only limited quantities of<br />

beverages compared with the quantity of beverages consumed in<br />

Denmark. . . . In those circumstances, a restriction of the quantity of<br />

products which may be marketed by importers is disproportionate to the<br />

objective pursued. "0<br />

In another case concerning the review of a Community legal act, the ECJ<br />

explained the full proportionality test as follows:<br />

[T]he principle of proportionality . . . requires that measures adopted by<br />

Community institutions should not exceed the limits of what is appropriate<br />

and necessary in order to attain the legitimate objectives pursued by the<br />

legislation in question, and where there is a choice between several<br />

appropriate measures, recourse must be had to the least onerous, and the<br />

disadvantages caused must not be disproportionate to the aims pursued<br />

111<br />

The application of the principle of proportionality in the area of fundamental<br />

rights is also illustrative. Whenever fundamental rights are restricted or interfered<br />

with by public authorities, the legislative or administrative measures will be assessed<br />

against the background of the principle of proportionality. This assessment is<br />

particularly relevant in areas covered by the ECHR and domestic constitutional law.<br />

Usually, the first stage of assessment is to identify the protected right or interest.<br />

One then moves on to identify the extent to which the right is interfered with or<br />

restricted. The next stage is to identify the reasons for that restriction. Finally, the<br />

last stage is to assess whether the interference was excessive or not. Restrictions<br />

have to be suitable, necessary, and proportionate. In this context, proportionality<br />

108. Case C-169/91, Stoke-on-Trent v. B&Q, 1992 E.C.R. 1-6625, 1-6658.<br />

109. Jans, supra note 91, at 248.<br />

110. Case 302/86, Comm'n v Denmark, 1988 E.C.R. 4607, 4632 (emphasis added) [hereinafter Danish<br />

Bottles]: see Case 44/79, Hauer v. Land Rheinland-Pfalz, 1979 E.C.R. 3727, 3749.<br />

111. Case T-13/99, Pfizer [2002] ECR 11-3305, paras 411-13; Case C-67/98, Questore di Verona v.<br />

Zenatti, 1999 E.C.R. 1-7289, 1-7316 (delegating the decision of whether domestic measure is<br />

disproportionate to the national courts).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 391 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

stricto sensu involves a "fair balance" between the disadvantages for the person<br />

whose rights are restricted and the weight of the legitimate aims pursued by the<br />

state. Interferences with fundamental rights need to be "proportionate to the policy<br />

aims that underlie them."" '<br />

The justification for balancing and proportionality stricto sensu was outlined<br />

above. In the area of fundamental rights, for instance, state measures that are<br />

necessary may still be disproportionate because the disadvantages caused to an<br />

individual are excessive, compared to the aims pursued by the state. A necessary<br />

measure may be proportionate when it just marginally impacts on fundamental<br />

rights. On the other hand, even a severe impact on fundamental rights, such as the<br />

shooting of a criminal, may, in individual circumstances, be the only possible way to<br />

achieve a specific objective. It is only after a finding of necessity that a careful<br />

balancing and weighing will come into play.' 3<br />

III. INTENSITY OF REVIEW<br />

In the above sections we have discussed substantive aspects of the principle of<br />

proportionality. This section focuses on the procedural sibling: the issue of intensity<br />

of review. The reason for including this topic here is the following. When courts<br />

apply a particular test to assess the legality of the reviewed measure, they will also<br />

have to determine the level and rigour of scrutiny with which they apply those tests.<br />

Intensity or standard of review determines how strictly courts assess the compliance<br />

of a domestic measure with the substantive requirements." ' The question is whether<br />

courts defer to the justifications provided by the national authorities or rather<br />

undertake an entirely independent review of the measure at issue.<br />

In ECHR law, this question has been conceptualized as "margin of<br />

appreciation." " ' 5 The intensity of review of national measures will depend on, among<br />

other things, the fundamental right concerned, the wording of particular provisions<br />

of the ECHR, the type of legitimate aim pursued by the member state, and whether<br />

common European standards exist." 1 6 The concept of margin of appreciation, which<br />

is closely linked to the principle of proportionality, concerns the degree of deference<br />

that the European Court of Human Rights shows towards national authorities in<br />

interpreting and applying the ECHR.<br />

Intensity of review is often treated as a free-standing concept, as the concept of<br />

standard of review in WTO law demonstrates. In contrast, in the analysis of the<br />

principle of proportionality in EC law the assessment of the nature of the<br />

proportionality test is often combined with an assessment of the intensity of review<br />

adopted by the courts in applying this test. Courts can, for instance, impose a very<br />

strict proportionality standard while largely deferring to the findings of the national<br />

112. Philip Sales & Ben Hooper, Proportionality and the Form of <strong>Law</strong>, 119 L. Q. REV. 426, 426 (2003).<br />

113. MICHAEL KRUGMANN, DER GRUNDSATZ DER VERHALTNISMABIGKEIT IM VOLKERRECHT<br />

[THE PRINCIPLE OF PROPORTIONALITY IN INTERNATIONAL LAW] 55 (2004).<br />

114. SNELL, supra note 95, at 212.<br />

115. Eva Brems, The Margin of Appreciation Doctrine in the Case-<strong>Law</strong> of the European Court of<br />

Human Rights, 56 ZEITSCHRIFr FOR AUSLANDISCHES OFFENTLICHES RECHT UND VOLKERRECHT<br />

[HEIDELBERG J. INT'L L.] 240, 242 (1996).<br />

116. See generally Brems, supra note 115; see also HOWARD YOUROW, THE MARGIN OF<br />

APPRECIATION DOCTRINE IN THE DYNAMICS OF THE EUROPEAN COURT OF HUMAN RIGHTS<br />

JURISPRUDENCE 185-86 (1996).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 392 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

authorities. This deferential review will make the proportionality assessment less<br />

rigorous than it seems at first glance. Proportionality taken together with varying<br />

degrees of intensity of review may be a very sharp or rather blunt weapon in the<br />

hands of the judiciary.<br />

A. Intensity of Review in EC <strong>Law</strong><br />

The close connection between the substantive requirements of proportionality<br />

and intensity of review is illustrated in the famous Fedesa judgment where the ECJ<br />

ruled that:<br />

[T]he principle of proportionality is one of the general principles of<br />

Community law. By virtue of that principle, the lawfulness of the<br />

prohibition of an economic activity is subject to the condition that the<br />

prohibitory measures are appropriate and necessary . . . when there is a<br />

choice between several appropriate measures recourse must be had to the<br />

least onerous, and the disadvantages caused must not be disproportionate<br />

to the aims pursued.<br />

However, with regard to judicial review of compliance with those conditions<br />

it must be stated that in matters concerning the common agricultural policy<br />

the Community legislature has a discretionary power .... Consequently,<br />

the legality of a measure adopted in that sphere can be affected only if the<br />

measure is manifestly inappropriate having regard to the objective which<br />

the competent institution is seeking to pursue .... "'<br />

The intensity of review may range from rigorous to very deferential. The<br />

overall degree of deference shown towards a reviewed measure will be determined<br />

by a variety of aspects, including the strictness of the examination of the underlying<br />

facts (and the necessity of the measure), the degree of justification required from<br />

national authorities, and the extent to which the court generally defers to the<br />

discretion of the authorities that took the initial decision. With regard to institutional<br />

considerations, courts do not show the same degree of deference to all institutions or<br />

actors involved. The case law of the ECJ serves as an illustrative example. The<br />

Court has regularly reviewed the activities of both member states and Community<br />

institutions. In many areas, the Court has adopted a more lenient standard of review<br />

towards the acts of Community institutions than of member states. 1 1 8 To give a<br />

concrete example, one may refer to Natalie McNelis' comparative study on the EC<br />

BSE case and the WTO EC - Hormones case." 9 McNelis concludes that the ECJ<br />

adopted a deferential approach in the BSE case because it trusted that the<br />

117. Case 331/88, The Queen v. Minister for Agriculture, Fisheries and Food ex parte Fedesa, 1990<br />

E.C.R. 1-4023, 1-4063 (emphasis added) [hereinafter Fedesa].<br />

118. Takis Tridimas, Proportionality in Community <strong>Law</strong>: Searching for the Appropriate Standard of<br />

Scrutiny, in THE PRINCIPLE OF PROPORTIONALITY IN THE LAWS OF EUROPE 66 (Evelyn Ellis ed., 1999).<br />

119. Case C-180/96, United Kingdom v Commission, 1998 E.C.R. 2265: Appellate Body Report,<br />

European Communities - Measures Concerning Meat and Meat Products, para. 117, WT/DS48/AB/R (Jan.<br />

16, 1998) [hereinafter EC - Hormones ABR], available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/english/tratop-e/dispu-e/hormab.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 393 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

Commission had acted in the Community interest.' 20 In areas such as the Common<br />

Agricultural Policy and economic policy, the Commission, as a specialist bureaucracy<br />

with considerable expertise, and as guardian of the EC Treaty, enjoys a wide margin<br />

of discretion, particularly as to the nature and extent of the measures which it<br />

adopts. 121 Similarly, the Court of First Instance, reviewing harmonizing Community<br />

legislation, held that "[tihe Community judicature is not entitled to substitute its<br />

assessment of the facts for that of the Community institutions, on which the Treaty<br />

confers sole responsibility for that duty.' ' 2 In this context, the review by the courts<br />

of the necessity of the measure (the second element of the proportionality test) will<br />

be limited. While the Court is deferential towards the policy choices of the<br />

Community institutions, it puts more emphasis on the procedural aspects leading to<br />

the adoption of the measure. 23 Those processes and guarantees (e.g. due process<br />

and transparency requirements) will be reviewed more strictly.<br />

The Court's review is stricter when member states' measures constitute<br />

potential obstacles to the free movement guarantees of the EC Internal Market. 12<br />

This is the proper area to draw parallels to the WTO judiciary judging WTO<br />

Members' actions.<br />

The grounds of justifications and issues involved equally affect the intensity of<br />

review in EC law. Political issues, such as national security or economic policy,<br />

generally entail a wide discretion and choice of measures for public authorities.<br />

Courts will be ill-suited to evaluate these policy choices concerning the collective or<br />

public interest. Furthermore, Member <strong>State</strong>s may have particular competence and<br />

expertise in certain areas which will lead courts to undertake a lighter review of the<br />

justifications provided by these states.' 25 Conversely, domestic measures aimed, for<br />

instance, at consumer protection have been scrutinized closely by the ECJ.1 26<br />

Consumer protection is an area closely linked to the EC's Internal Market where the<br />

Court has gained considerable experience. Equally, courts tend to adopt a stricter<br />

approach when individual rights and interests are at stake, such as the restriction of<br />

fundamental rights and market freedoms.<br />

Additionally, measures diverging from the majoritarian view or practice of the<br />

member states may be assessed more strictly than measures in areas where a<br />

consensus among the member states does not (yet) exist.<br />

120. See Natalie McNelis, The Role of Judge in the EU and WTO. Lessons from the BSE and<br />

Hormones Cases, 4 J. INT'L ECON. L. 189, 200-01 (2001).<br />

121. Case 55/75, Balkan-Import-Export v. Hauptzollamt Berlin-Packhof, 1976 E.C.R. 19, 30. The<br />

expertise argument is often invoked in the WTrO context (greater expertise of domestic agencies and<br />

decision-making processes). For an overview, see MATTHIAS OESCH, STANDARDS OF REVIEW IN WTO<br />

DISPUTE RESOLUTION 55-57 (2004).<br />

122. Case T-13/99, Pfizer, 2002 E.C.R. 11-3305, para. 169. See also Case C-84/94, United Kingdom v.<br />

Council, 1996 E.C.R. 1-5755 paras. 57-67 [hereinafter Working Time Directive].<br />

123. Joanne Scott, International Trade and Environmental Governance: Relating Rules (and<br />

Standards) in the EU and WTO, 15 EURO. J. INT'L L. 307, 319 (2004).<br />

124. Compare Case C-369/89, Piageme v. BVBA Peeters, 1991 E.C.R. 1-2971 (stating that Article 30<br />

of the EEC Treaty precludes labeling requirement imposed by member state) with Case C-51/93, Meyhui v.<br />

Schott Zweisel Glaswerke, 1994 E.C.R. 1-3879 (labeling requirement imposed by a Directive).<br />

125. Sean Pager, Strictness vs. Discretion: The European Court of Justice's Variable Vision of Gender<br />

Equality, 51 AM. J. COMP. L. 553, 556 (2003).<br />

126. See German Beer, supra note 107; see also Case 261/81 Rau [1982] ECR 3961.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 394 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

B. Standard of Review in WTO <strong>Law</strong><br />

In the WTO legal order, the concept of standard of review determines the<br />

nature and intensity of review exercised by the WTO judiciary. Similar to intensity<br />

of review in EC law, it is about the depth with which the challenged national<br />

measures are scrutinized.' 27 The underlying concern for WTO law is to what extent<br />

judges (need to) defer to national findings of facts and law and whether the judges<br />

may adopt different factual and legal conclusions than the domestic authorities<br />

under review (i.e., second guess the national determinations). 2 '<br />

Through its central role in dispute settlement, standard of review influences the<br />

vertical relationship between supranational adjudicators and makers of sovereign<br />

member states. 2 9 It allocates the power to decide, in the last instance, on sensitive<br />

issues of law and fact. 3 " It is for this reason that standard of review has been<br />

recognized as an important concept of the WTO legal order and features<br />

prominently in the Panel and AB reports, as well as in the academic literature.'<br />

Usually, it is treated as a free-standing concept with a bearing on the conduct of the<br />

panel review of domestic measures. We attempt to situate it in the context of the<br />

overall subject of this article.<br />

The historical developments leading to the current standards of review have<br />

been explored elsewhere and need not be repeated here.' 32 It suffices to say that<br />

there is no explicit provision on standard of review in the GATT or the WTO<br />

Agreements, except for Article 17.6 of the Agreement on Implementation of Article<br />

VI of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade.' 33<br />

In the EC- Hormones case, the appellate body seized the opportunity to define<br />

a general standard of review for all WTO Agreements (except for those which<br />

prescribe a different standard).' The appellate body carefully ruled that the<br />

standard of review "must reflect the balance established . . . between the<br />

jurisdictional competences conceded by the Members to the WTO and the<br />

jurisdictional competences retained by the Members for themselves.', 135 Referring to<br />

DSU Article 11 as the textual basis, the AB declared the proper standard of review<br />

to be an "objective assessment of the matter" by the panel. 3 6 The relevant part of<br />

DSU Article 11 reads as follows:<br />

127. Matthias Oesch, Standards of Review in Dispute Resolution, 6 J. INT'L ECON. L. 635, 637 (2003).<br />

128. Id. at 637-38.<br />

129. See Stefan Zleptnig, The Standard of Review in WTO <strong>Law</strong>: An Analysis of <strong>Law</strong>, Legitimacy and<br />

the Distribution of Legal and Political Authority, 13 EURO. Bus. L. REV. 427, 456 (2002).<br />

130. See id. at 456-57.<br />

131. There is now considerable literature on this issue. See Stephen P. Croley & John H. Jackson,<br />

WTO Dispute Procedures, Standard of Review, and Deference to National Governments, 90 AM. J. INT'L L.<br />

193 (1996); see also OESCH, supra note 121 (discussing different approaches to standards of review).<br />

132. See OESCH, supra note 121, at ch. 4 (discussing GATT 1947 and its development of the notion of<br />

standard of review).<br />

133. See generally James Durling, Deference, But Only When Due: WTO Review of Anti-Dumping<br />

Measures, 6 J. INT'L ECON. L. 125 (2003) (discussing Article 17.6 of the Agreement on the Implementation<br />

of Art. VI of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade [hereinafter "Anti-Dumping Agreement"]).<br />

134. EC- Hormones ABR, supra note 119, para. 117.<br />

135. Id. para. 115.<br />

136. Id. para. 116.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 395 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

[A] panel should make an objective assessment of the matter before it,<br />

including an objective assessment of the facts of the case and the<br />

applicability of and conformity with the relevant covered agreements. 137<br />

In Hormones the AB ruled out two other possible standards of review. Both<br />

the de novo review (in which the panel substitutes its findings for that of the national<br />

authorities) and the total deference standard were rejected as inappropriate for the<br />

WTO dispute settlement system. 3<br />

The "objective assessment" standard itself is rather vague. It does not<br />

necessarily provide for precise substantive guidance regarding the nature and<br />

intensity of review exercised by the panels. Different authors have recently pointed<br />

out that, as a consequence, the appropriate standard of review is to be defined<br />

independently under each WTO agreement. For instance, panels will review<br />

national measures covered by the trade remedy agreements (e.g., anti-dumping,<br />

safeguards, and countervailing duties) differently from measures covered by the SPS<br />

and TBT Agreements or the GATT. 3 9<br />

The intensity of review set forth in DSU Article 11 relates to two different but<br />

interrelated aspects, the review of facts and law.' 0 The review of facts involves two<br />

steps. First, it relates to the process of fact-finding (the raw evidence) by domestic<br />

authorities.' The panel will review whether factual evidence was properly and<br />

sufficiently established.' 42 Second, it relates to the conclusions that national<br />

authorities draw from that factual evidence. 4 3 In their evaluation of raw evidence,<br />

WTO Members are usually granted a certain margin of discretion, subject to the<br />

condition that they adequately explain and justify how they reached their<br />

4<br />

conclusion.'<br />

Under the WTO trade remedy agreements, the panels' role is to review<br />

investigations and findings made by national authorities. Panels do not have the<br />

power to redo the original investigation and substitute their findings for that of<br />

national authorities (de novo review). They may, however, scrutinize whether the<br />

authorities respected the procedural requirements imposed on the domestic<br />

decision-making process and provided a "reasoned and adequate explanation" for<br />

their determinations. 14<br />

137. Understanding on Rules and Procedures Governing the Settlement of Disputes, Apr. 15, 1994,<br />

Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, Annex 2, Legal Instruments- Results<br />

of the Uruguay Round, 33 I.L.M. 1125 (1994) [hereinafter DSU], available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/English/docs-e/legal-e/28-dsu.pdf.<br />

138. EC- Hormones ABR, supra note 119, para. 117.<br />

139. See generally Holger Spamann, Standard of Review for World Trade Organization Panels in<br />

Trade Remedy Cases: a Critical Analysis, 38 J. WORLD TRADE 509 (2004) (arguing that national authorities<br />

would not necessarily fare worse under a de novo standard of review of trade measures); see also Claus-<br />

Dieter Ehlermann & Nicolas Lockhart, Standard of Review in WTO <strong>Law</strong>, 7 J. INT'L ECON. L. 491 (2004)<br />

(examining the review of trade remedy measures, SPS and TBT measures, and measures covered by the<br />

GATr 1994).<br />

140. Oesch, supra note 127, at 639.<br />

141. Id.<br />

142. Id.<br />

143. Id.<br />

144. Id. at 640-41.<br />

145. Appellate Body Report, United <strong>State</strong>s - Safeguard Measures on Imports of Fresh, Chilled or<br />

Frozen Lamb Meat from New Zealand and Australia, para. 103, WT/DS177/AB/R (May 16, 2001)<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 396 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

The following quote from US - Cotton Yarn summarizes the key elements of<br />

the standard of review as applied in this trade remedy case:<br />

[P]anels must examine whether the competent authority has evaluated all<br />

relevant factors; they must assess whether the competent authority has<br />

examined all the pertinent facts and assessed whether an adequate<br />

explanation has been provided as to how those facts support the<br />

determination; and they must also consider whether the competent<br />

authority's explanation addresses fully the nature and complexities of the<br />

data and responds to other plausible interpretations of the data. However,<br />

panels must not conduct a de novo review of the evidence nor substitute<br />

their judgement for that of the competent authority. 46<br />

The structure of review under the SPS and TBT Agreements will be different.<br />

Panels do not necessarily need to defer to formal investigations conducted at the<br />

national level. They will often be the first body to formally assess evidence, such as<br />

scientific justifications submitted in support of a particular domestic measure. Panels<br />

will then be less constrained in reviewing domestic fact-finding than under the trade<br />

remedy agreements. Under the GAT-F, panels may be in a similar position since<br />

they are often assessing facts which have neither been previously examined nor<br />

determined in formal procedures. Again, there may be no need to defer to the<br />

formal findings of domestic authorities. Regarding standard of review under the SPS<br />

Agreement, the AB once held:<br />

[W]ithin the bounds of their obligation under Article 11 to make an<br />

objective assessment of the facts of the case, panels enjoy a "margin of<br />

discretion" as triers of fact. Panels are thus "not required to accord to<br />

factual evidence of the parties the same meaning and weight as do the<br />

parties" and may properly "determine that certain elements of evidence<br />

should be accorded more weight than other elements."1 ' 7<br />

The review of law determines the consistency of a national measure (on the<br />

basis of established evidence) with the WTO Agreements and the extent to which<br />

panels can review the interpretation of WTO law submitted by the Members. In this<br />

area, it seems undisputed that the correct interpretation of the WTO Agreements is<br />

a matter for the panels and the AB, and there is no need to show deference towards<br />

national authorities. 14<br />

Standard of review in WTO law is a complex concept. It is hybrid in nature,<br />

due to "the interplay of substantive and procedural rules which, together, specify the<br />

role of Panels when reviewing national authorities' determinations." 149 ' The nature<br />

and intensity of review under the WTO Agreements depends on various factors. It<br />

(emphasis omitted) [hereinafter US - Lamb Meat], available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/english/tratop-e/dispu-e/cases-e/ds l77-e.pdf.<br />

146. US - Cotton Yarn, supra note 63, para. 74.<br />

147. Appellate Body Report, Japan - Affecting the Importation of Apples, para. 22t,<br />

WT/DS245/AB/R (November 26, 2003) (citations omitted) [hereinafter Japan - Apples], available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/english/tratop-e/dispu-e/245-abr-e.pdf.<br />

148. OESCH, supra note 121, at 30-33.<br />

149. Spamann, supra note 139, at 514.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 397 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

is relevant whether domestic authorities already conducted formal investigations<br />

which may include procedural guarantees for those affected by the decision-making<br />

process. Another issue is the expertise of the domestic decision-makers. On the<br />

other hand, panels may be the first to review evidence submitted to justify a<br />

particular measure.<br />

The way in which the review is conducted and the depth of scrutiny adopted by<br />

the panels will have a crucial impact on the substantive findings of the panels. To<br />

illustrate this point, we can refer to the necessity (or least trade-restrictiveness)<br />

requirement. 5 The panel will make a finding on the necessity of a domestic measure<br />

by taking into account and balancing a range of substantive, procedural, and factual<br />

criteria. Legal principles and substantive tests are hereby closely intertwined with<br />

the concept of standard of review, and the relationship between these different<br />

concepts will be one of mutual influence and dependence. The intensity of review<br />

strongly impacts on the court's assessment of the compliance of the reviewed<br />

measure with the substantive treaty requirements. It is this matrix-type relationship<br />

between substantive and procedural standards which governs the application of the<br />

principle of proportionality and similar tests in the judicial process.<br />

IV.<br />

PROPORTIONALITY IN PUBLIC INTERNATIONAL LAW<br />

The principle of proportionality has been extensively discussed in the context of<br />

domestic and EC law. In those areas, it is usually applied to the relationship<br />

between states and citizens and the exercise of legislative or regulatory competence.<br />

In addition, proportionality in public international law governs the relationship<br />

between equal and sovereign states. There are many areas of public international<br />

law where the principle of proportionality plays an important role. At the same<br />

time, it is difficult to identify a coherent substantive content of proportionality across<br />

the whole range of public international law. We focus on some core areas where<br />

proportionality plays a crucial role in determining the scope of international norms<br />

and the powers that states may exercise vis-A-vis other states and their populations.<br />

A. Countermeasures<br />

The principle of proportionality plays a prominent role in the law of<br />

international countermeasures. We will discuss proportionality and countermeasures<br />

generally and then turn to relevant case law and the important International <strong>Law</strong><br />

Commission Articles on Responsibility of <strong>State</strong>s for Internationally Wrongful Acts.<br />

Generally, proportionality in the law of countermeasures determines the extent<br />

to which countermeasures in response to wrongful acts are permissible, thus<br />

regulating both the nature and intensity of the response. 5 ' Proportionality imposes<br />

limitations on the unilateral power to take countermeasures. The precise normative<br />

content of proportionality in the area of countermeasures, however, is more difficult<br />

to determine. It includes at least two interconnected aspects: "[p]roportionality<br />

requires not only employing the means appropriate to the aim chosen, but implies,<br />

150. Alexy, supra note 38, at 66.<br />

151. Enzo Cannizzaro, The Role of Proportionality in the <strong>Law</strong> of International Countermeasures, 12<br />

EURO. J. INT'L L. 889, 915-16 (2001).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 398 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

above all, an assessment of the appropriateness of the aim itself."' 52 The latter aspect<br />

relates to the aim pursued by a state in response to wrongful conduct by another<br />

state. The aim itself needs to be appropriate and reasonable in the context of the<br />

situation and the breached rule.' 3 Once the appropriateness of the aim pursued has<br />

been established, countermeasures are required to be proportionate to the original<br />

breach.<br />

Proportionality featured prominently in the Gabcikovo-Nagymaros (Hungary<br />

v. Slovakia) case before the ICJ. The Court's succinct formula relating to<br />

proportionality was that "the effects of a countermeasure must be commensurate<br />

with the injury suffered, taking account of the rights in question."' 54 The<br />

countermeasure at issue- Czechoslovakia had diverted the river Danube-was<br />

found disproportionate and unlawful by the Court:<br />

Czechoslovakia, by unilaterally assuming control of a shared resource, and<br />

thereby depriving Hungary of its right to an equitable and reasonable<br />

share of the natural resources of the Danube-with the continuing effects<br />

of the diversion of these waters on the ecology of the riparian area of the<br />

Szigetk6z-failed to respect the proportionality which is required by<br />

international law.' 5<br />

The ICJ did not only evaluate the countermeasure in purely quantitative terms<br />

(the injury suffered), but took account of other qualitative factors as well (in<br />

particular, the parties' rights involved). Hungary, for instance, which had committed<br />

the original wrongful act, still had the right to an "equitable and reasonable share of<br />

the natural resources of the Danube." ' 6 It was by taking the countermeasures at<br />

issue that Czechoslovakia had deprived Hungary of this right and thus violated the<br />

principle of proportionality.<br />

Article 51 of the recent ILC Articles on Responsibility of <strong>State</strong>s for<br />

Internationally Wrongful Acts is entitled "Proportionality." 15' This provision<br />

reaffirms the ICJ's approach in Gabcikovo-Nagymaros and reads as follows:<br />

"Countermeasures must be commensurate with the injury suffered, taking into<br />

'<br />

account the gravity of the internationally wrongful act and the rights in question.<br />

The Commentaries to the Draft Articles explain the reasoning behind Article<br />

51 and outline the two components of the proportionality requirement. The first<br />

component is quantitative and assesses the injury suffered by the injured state. The<br />

152. Id. at 897 (emphasis added).<br />

153. Id. at 899.<br />

154. Gabcikovo-Nagymaros Project (Hung. v. Slovk.), 1997 I.C.J. 7, 56 (Sept. 25).<br />

155. Id.<br />

156. Id. para. 85.<br />

157. See also U.N. International <strong>Law</strong> Commission, Responsibility of <strong>State</strong>s for Internationally<br />

Wrongful Acts, (adopted at the Commission's fifty-third session in 2001 and submitted in the UN General<br />

Assembly as a part of the Commission's work) and Commentaries to the Draft Articles on Responsibility of<br />

<strong>State</strong>s for Internationally Wrongful Acts, U.N. GAOR 56th Sess., Supp. No. 10, art. 51, para. 4, U.N. Doc<br />

A/56/10 (2001) [hereinafter International <strong>Law</strong> Commission's Articles], available at<br />

http://untreaty.un.org/ilc/reports/2001/2001report.htm (search by chapter "<strong>State</strong> Responsibility"). See also<br />

James Crawford et al. The ILC's Articles on Responsibility of <strong>State</strong>s for Internationally Wrongful Acts:<br />

Completion of the Second Reading 12 EUR. J. INT'L. L. 963-991 (2007).<br />

158. Id. art. 51.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 399 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

second component is qualitative and requires that additional factors be taken into<br />

account, such as the "importance of the interest protected by the rule infringed and<br />

the seriousness of the breach. '" ' Proportionality of countermeasures will therefore<br />

be assessed in relation to the injury suffered, while the gravity of the wrongful act,<br />

the importance of the protected interests, and the impact on rights of both the<br />

injured and the responsible states are also taken into account and balanced against<br />

one another.<br />

Proportionality as a legal principle governing the relationship between the<br />

wrongful act and the countermeasure refines the basic requirement in Article 49 of<br />

the Draft Articles. This provision, which states the objects and limits of<br />

countermeasures, requires that they be taken only to induce the state responsible for<br />

the wrongful act to comply with its obligations.' 6 0 In this respect, proportionality<br />

goes beyond a mere necessity test since it is not only relevant whether the<br />

countermeasure was necessary to achieve compliance. It is possible that<br />

countermeasures are considered disproportionate in circumstances where they go<br />

beyond what is necessary to achieve compliance and instead pursue a punitive<br />

objective .<br />

B. Use of Force and Armed Conflicts' 62<br />

The principle of proportionality is an equally important concept for the law on<br />

the use of force (jus ad bellum) and the law of armed conflicts (/us in bello)' 6 In the<br />

first case, it relates to the response to a particular attack and, in the second case, it<br />

relates to the conduct of that response and the balance that needs to be struck<br />

between military objectives and the damages inflicted on the enemy. '6 1<br />

Proportionality is particularly interesting and controversial in these fields, given the<br />

significant and unalterable consequences which the interpretation and application of<br />

this principle may have. Moreover, the application of proportionality in these<br />

circumstances is useful to highlight its problems and limitations. In her 1993 article<br />

on proportionality and force in international law, Judith Gail Gardam critically notes<br />

that:<br />

Despite the potential of proportionality to undermine pleas of selfdefence,<br />

at no time has much attention been paid to its requirements. This<br />

omission is somewhat surprising, given the status of proportionality as one<br />

of the determinants of the legality of a state's use of force. Moreover, it<br />

remains relevant throughout the conflict 65<br />

In the law relating to the right to use force, proportionality refers to a<br />

belligerent's response to a grievance. The resort to force under the UN Charter is<br />

159. Id. art. 51, para. 6.<br />

160. Id. art. 49.<br />

161. Id. art. 49, para. 7.<br />

162. The authors gratefully acknowledge the research of Daniel Geron, which has been of assistance<br />

to this section.<br />

163. Judith Gardam, Proportionality and Force in International <strong>Law</strong>, 87 AM. J. INT'L L. 391, 391<br />

(1993); JUDITH GARDAM, NECESSITY, PROPORTIONALITY AND THE USE OF FORCE BY STATES 32-53<br />

(2004).<br />

164. Id., at 391.<br />

165. Id. at 404 (citation omitted).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 400 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

limited by the customary law requirement that it be proportionate to the unlawful<br />

aggression which caused it. Article 51 of the UN Charter prohibits the use of force<br />

other than in self-defense, but it does not mention the principle of proportionality<br />

expressly. The International Court of Justice (ICJ) in Military and Paramilitary<br />

Activities in and against Nicaragua referred to the well-established rule of customary<br />

international law that "self-defence would warrant only measures which are<br />

proportional to the armed attack and necessary to respond to it . . . ."'66 In its<br />

Advisory Opinion on the Threat or Use of Nuclear Weapons, the ICJ referred back to<br />

its Nicaragua decision and held:<br />

The submission of the exercise of the right of self-defence to the<br />

conditions of necessity and proportionality is a rule of customary<br />

international law .... This dual condition applies equally to Article 51 of<br />

the Charter, whatever the means of force employed. The proportionality<br />

principle may thus not in itself exclude the use of nuclear weapons in selfdefence<br />

in all circumstances. But at the same time, a use of force that is<br />

proportionate under the law of self-defence, must, in order to be lawful,<br />

also meet the requirements of the law applicable in armed conflict which<br />

comprise in particular the principles and rules of humanitarian law. 6 1<br />

The Court's jurisprudence highlights the requirement that actions of selfdefense<br />

shall observe both the criteria of necessity and proportionality. The role of<br />

proportionality in this context is to impose limitations on lawful self-defense and to<br />

determine the harm that may be done to others. The means employed shall be<br />

necessary to respond to, and fend off, a particular attack and be proportionate in<br />

relation to the severity of the attack. To give a concrete example, it would be<br />

disproportionate to respond to a minor raid across the border with the use of nuclear<br />

weapons.<br />

Taking a close look at the proportionality requirement, Judge Higgins has<br />

raised the fundamental question: "proportionate in respect of what?' 6 She then<br />

argued that proportionality usually relates to the injury received by a single<br />

incident.' 69 In cases of continuing aggression or invasion, proportionality might not<br />

relate to specific injuries as such, but to the overall objective of ending or reversing<br />

the aggression. 7 ' With regard to the possible use of nuclear weapons in self-defense,<br />

the ICJ's Advisory Opinion on the Threat or Use of Nuclear Weapons recognized still<br />

further factors involved in the assessment of proportionality, for instance the risks of<br />

escalating the conflict. 71<br />

In the Oil Platforms case, the ICJ considered two actions by the U.S. against<br />

Iranian targets to determine whether the self-defense responses were necessary and<br />

166. Military and Paramilitary Activities (Nicar. v. U.S.), 1986 I.C.J. 14, paras. 176, 194 (June 27),<br />

available at http://www.icj-cij.org/icjwww/icases/inus/inus-ijudgment/inus-ijudgment-19860627.pdf.<br />

167. Legality of the Threat or Use of Nuclear Weapons, Advisory Opinion, 1996 I.C.J. 226 (July 8)<br />

paras. 41-42 (emphasis added) [hereinafter Nuclear Weapons], available at http://www.icjcij.org/icjwww/icases/iunan/iunanframe.htm.<br />

168. ROSALYN HIGGINS, PROBLEMS AND PROCESS. INTERNATIONAL LAW AND How WE USE IT<br />

231(1994) (quotes omitted).<br />

169. Id.<br />

170. Id. at 231-232.<br />

171. Nuclear Weapons, supra note 167, para. 43.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 401 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

proportionate to the Iranian attack. 72 The United <strong>State</strong>s failed to convince the ICJ<br />

that its attacks on the platforms qualified as "necessary" acts of self-defense against<br />

the Iranian attacks. 7 3 There is an interesting statement on the relationship between<br />

necessity and proportionality in the Court's decision. Referring to the U.S. attack of<br />

October 19, 1987, the ICJ stated that, had it found this attack to be a necessary<br />

response to the Iranian attack, it might have been proportionate. 74 With regard to<br />

other U.S. attacks of 1988, which were part of a broader operation entitled<br />

"Operation Praying Mantis," the Court held that neither the operation as a whole<br />

nor the more specific attacks could be regarded as "proportionate use of force in<br />

self-defence. "17<br />

The relevant parameters of the proportionality principle are even more<br />

complicated in the debate over the legality of the doctrine of anticipatory selfdefense.<br />

The main question is whether the force used in anticipation of an attack is<br />

proportionate to the threat. Brownlie, for instance, has put forward some objection<br />

to anticipatory self-defense on the basis that it may be contrary to the principle of<br />

proportionality. 176 More fully, his argument goes as follows:<br />

It is possible that in a very limited number of situations force might be a<br />

reaction proportionate to the danger where there is unequivocal evidence<br />

of an intention to launch a devastating attack almost immediately.<br />

However, in the great majority of cases to commit a state to an actual<br />

conflict when there is only circumstantial evidence of impending attack<br />

would be to act in a manner which disregarded the requirement of<br />

proportionality.' 77<br />

The substantive law of armed conflicts is also based on the requirements of<br />

proportionality. In the context of jus in bello proportionality refers to the balance to<br />

be struck between the achievement of a military goal and the cost in terms of lives of<br />

combatants and the civilian population. Proportionality is considered to be a<br />

fundamental principle of the law of armed conflict. 178 It is not always expressed as<br />

"proportionality" in the particular rules of the law of war, but its presence can be<br />

clearly seen to underpin and inspire many of the rules in this area.1 7 1<br />

Proportionality is a determining factor in a variety of situations, including the<br />

selection of targets, the means and methods of attack, and the conduct of the attack<br />

itself.' The underlying concern is to limit casualties and damages done to others "to<br />

what is proportionate to the achievement of the military goal.''. The choice of the<br />

means of warfare and the damages that may result is clearly restricted by the<br />

172. Oil Platforms (Iran v. U. S.), 2003 I.C.J. 161 (Nov. 6).<br />

173. Id. para. 76.<br />

174. Id. para. 77.<br />

175. Id.<br />

176. IAN BROWNLIE, INTERNATIONAL LAW AND THE USE OF FORCE BY STATES 261-262 (1963).<br />

177. Id. at 259.<br />

178. Gardam, supra note 163, at 391.<br />

179. See generally Convention Respecting the <strong>Law</strong>s and Customs of War on Land, Annex to the<br />

Hague Convention, U.S. - Neth., Oct. 18, 1907, 36 Stat. 2277 [hereinafter Hague IV]; Protocol Additional<br />

to the Geneva Convention of 12 August 1949 and Relating to the Protection of Victims of International<br />

Armed Conflicts, June 8, 1977, 1125 U.N.T.S. 3 [hereinafter Protocol I].<br />

180. Gardam, supra note 163, at 407.<br />

181. Id. at 406.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 402 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

principle of proportionality. In this context, decision-makers and the military have<br />

to undertake a cost-benefit analysis to assess the damages that an action may cause,<br />

for instance, to non-combatants. It is hardly surprising that this involves a complex<br />

balancing of competing goals that needs to be reconciled by the military before and<br />

during their actions, and an assessment of those actions will take place by judges of<br />

those actions ex post.<br />

The difficulties in applying the principle of proportionality in this area were<br />

presented in a Report to the Prosecutor at the International Criminal Tribunal for<br />

the Former Yugoslavia (ICTY):<br />

The main problem with the principle of proportionality is not whether or<br />

not it exists but what it means and how it is to be applied. It is relatively<br />

simple to state that there must be an acceptable relation between the<br />

legitimate destructive effect and undesirable collateral effects. . . . It is<br />

much easier to formulate the principle of proportionality in general terms<br />

than it is to apply it to a particular set of circumstances because the<br />

comparison is often between unlike quantities and values. One cannot<br />

easily assess the value of innocent human lives as opposed to capturing a<br />

particular military objective.<br />

The questions which remain unresolved once one decides to apply<br />

the principle of proportionality include the following:<br />

(a) What are the relative values to be assigned to the military<br />

advantage gained and to the injury to non-combatants and/or the damage<br />

to civilian objects? ...<br />

(c) What is the standard of measurement in time or space? and<br />

(d) To what extent is a military commander obligated to expose his<br />

own forces to danger in order to limit civilian casualties or damage to<br />

civilian objects?<br />

The answers to these questions are not simple. It may be necessary to<br />

resolve them on a case by case basis, and the answers may differ<br />

depending on the background and values of the decision maker. It is<br />

unlikely that a human rights lawyer and an experienced combat<br />

commander would assign the same relative values to military advantage<br />

and to injury to non-combatants.'<br />

182. Id. at 406.; Final Report to the Prosecutor by the Committee Established to Review the NATO<br />

Bombing Campaign Against the Federal Republic of Yugoslavia. ICTR PR/P.I.S./510-E, paras. 48-50 (June<br />

8. 2000), reprinted in 39 I.L.M. 1257.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 403 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

C. Maritime Delimitation<br />

Finally, we may refer to the area of maritime delimitation, where<br />

proportionality appears as an element of equity intended to guide the decisionmaking<br />

process." 3 Recourse to the concept of proportionality is made to evaluate<br />

the award of continental shelf land to states.<br />

D. Conclusion<br />

We have shown that the principle of proportionality is an essential concept in<br />

international law. Yet its content remains diffuse, and the different nuances and<br />

functions vary from area to area. Generally, proportionality in international law is<br />

about the limits of unilateral state action necessary to pursue a legitimate objective.<br />

In some instances, proportionality goes further than that. In addition to the<br />

necessity of a state action, proportionality requires a complex balancing of<br />

quantitative and qualitative factors, including competing rights, values and interests.<br />

This is particularly pertinent in the areas of countermeasures and the use of force.<br />

The international legal system traditionally lacks the element of subordination<br />

that can be found in the domestic context. Within this legal order, the principle of<br />

proportionality plays an important role as a standard to determine how far sovereign<br />

states can go in their relationships with other states. One core function of<br />

proportionality in international law is to impose functional limitations on the<br />

exercise of state powers. In this context, proportionality appears in two different<br />

ways. First, it serves as an overarching principle guiding the relationship between,<br />

and the scope of, other rules and principles. One function of principles in<br />

international law is to fill gaps and to avoid a non liquet, and this is where<br />

proportionality may come into play. Second, proportionality may be part of the<br />

substantive law on countermeasures, self-defense, or armed conflicts, and thereby<br />

establishes positive obligations for state actions in those areas.<br />

V. BALANCING IN US CONSTITUTIONAL LAW: THE INTERSTATE<br />

COMMERCE CLAUSE<br />

The Interstate Commerce Clause (ICC) is an important and complex feature of<br />

U.S. constitutional law.' 8 ' Broadly speaking, the ICC covers two different aspects.<br />

First, it grants Congress the power to legislate on interstate commerce matters.<br />

186<br />

Second, it imposes limitations on states when interfering with interstate commerce.<br />

The ICC can be said to fulfill a similar function to the free movement provisions in<br />

183. HIGGINS, supra note 168, ch. 13.<br />

184. U.S. CONST. art. I, § 8, cl. 3 (providing that Congress shall have power to "regulate Commerce<br />

with foreign Nations, and among the several <strong>State</strong>s, and with the Indian Tribes"). There is considerable<br />

literature on the development and current interpretation of the Commerce Clause. See generally<br />

LAURENCE TRIBE, AMERICAN CONSTITUTIONAL LAW § 6 (3d ed. 2000); Michael <strong>Law</strong>rence, Toward a<br />

More Coherent Dormant Commerce Clause: A Proposed Unitary Framework, 21 HARV. J. L. & PUB. POL'Y<br />

395 (1998).<br />

185. <strong>Law</strong>rence, supra note 184, at 407.<br />

186. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 404 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

EC law. 8 7 1 Furthermore, the ICC has sometimes been compared to the GATT, with<br />

scholars attempting to gain some useful insights from the ICC doctrine for GAIT<br />

law. 88 The ICC has many different facets which will not be discussed in detail here.<br />

However, particularly relevant for the scope of this paper is the difference under the<br />

ICC between (a) the strict necessity test applied to discriminatory regulation and (b)<br />

the balancing approach applied to non-discriminatory<br />

9<br />

regulation. Whenever state<br />

regulation affects interstate commerce, even by doing so incidentally, it needs to<br />

satisfy those tests; otherwise it will be struck down as unconstitutional.' 90 The<br />

balancing approach seems to resemble the proportionality analysis in EC law.<br />

According to both of these concepts, the judges will ultimately assess whether<br />

legitimate interests sought by public authorities outweigh the burden imposed on<br />

free trade or other protected rights and interests.<br />

The applicable tests of review depend on whether state regulation discriminates<br />

against out-of-state or interstate commerce. If there is discrimination, state<br />

regulation will be measured against a strict standard, as opposed to the more<br />

deferential balancing test applied to non-discriminatory measures.""<br />

If state regulation is discriminatory against interstate commerce, it is subject to<br />

strict judicial scrutiny and may only be upheld if two conditions are fulfilled. First,<br />

the measure must pursue a legitimate local purpose.' 92 <strong>State</strong> interests may, for<br />

instance, involve public health or safety, environmental protection or the prevention<br />

of consumer fraud. 9 Second, even if state regulation pursues a legitimate purpose, it<br />

will be considered unlawful if there are less discriminatory means by which the state<br />

could achieve the same purpose.' 94 The burden is on the state to prove the necessity<br />

of its measure. 9 This approach has been called the heightened scrutiny test.'1 6 The<br />

courts may adopt different degrees of scrutiny under such a less restrictive means<br />

test. In C & A Carbone v. Town of Clarkstown, for instance, the Supreme Court<br />

formulated a particularly strict standard of scrutiny:<br />

Discrimination against interstate commerce in favor of local business or<br />

investment is per se invalid, save in a narrow class of cases in which the<br />

187. GEORGE BERMANN ET AL., CASES AND MATERIALS ON EUROPEAN UNION LAW 452 (2d ed.<br />

2002).<br />

188. Robert Howse, Managing the Interface between International Trade and the Regulatory <strong>State</strong>:<br />

What Lessons Should (and Should Not) Be Drawn from the Jurisprudence of the United <strong>State</strong>s Dormant<br />

Commerce Clause, in REGULATORY BARRIERS AND THE PRINCIPLE OF NON-DISCRIMINATION IN WORLD<br />

TRADE LAW, 2 WORLD TRADE FORUM 139-66 (Thomas Cottier & Petros Mavroidis eds. 2000).<br />

189. TRIBE, supra note 184, at 1049-51.<br />

190. Id.<br />

191. One of the justifications provided for a strict standard for discriminatory measures is the political<br />

representation argument. It says that lawmakers may be exposed to pressures from the domestic<br />

constituency, which leads lawmakers to take decisions harmful to others who are not represented in the<br />

domestic political process (for instance, out-of-state companies). Courts should therefore only show<br />

deference towards democratic decisions if all interests affected have adequately been represented in the<br />

political process. See TRIBE, supra note 184. at 1051-55.<br />

192. TRIBE, supra note 184, at 1049-51.<br />

193. JEROME BARRON & THOMAS DIENES. CONSTITUTIONAL LAW IN A NUTSHELL 116 (1999).<br />

194. TRIBE, supra note 184, at 1049-51.<br />

195. Daniel Farber & Robert Hudec, Free Trade and the Regulatory <strong>State</strong>: A GA TT's-Eye View of the<br />

Dormant Commerce Clause, 47 VAND. L. REV. 1401, 1412-13 (1994).<br />

196. BARRON & DIENES, supra note 193, at 114.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 405 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

municipality can demonstrate, under vigorous scrutiny, that it has no other<br />

means to advance a legitimate local interest. . . . [A]rguments [that the<br />

municipality has no other means to advance a legitimate local interest]<br />

must be rejected absent the clearest showing that the unobstructed flow of<br />

interstate commerce itself is unable to solve the local problem ...."'<br />

Conversely, non-discriminatory measures with only incidental effects on<br />

interstate commerce are subject to a lighter balancing test. '9 The reason for this test<br />

is that state regulation, even in the absence of discrimination, may still place an<br />

undue or excessive burden on interstate commerce. 9 Courts, adopting the<br />

balancing test, will inquire whether legitimate regulatory interests of the state<br />

outweigh the impediment to free movement of interstate commerce." There is also<br />

an additional least-restrictive-means requirement which is less strict than the one<br />

applied to discriminatory measures.21 This ad hoc balancing test was elaborated by<br />

the Supreme Court in Pike v. Bruce Church:<br />

Where the state regulates even-handedly to effectuate a legitimate local<br />

public interest, and its effects on interstate commerce are only incidental,<br />

it will be upheld unless the burden imposed on such commerce is clearly<br />

excessive in relation to the putative local benefits. If a legitimate local<br />

purpose is found, then the question becomes one of degree. And the<br />

extent of the burden that will be tolerated will of course depend on the<br />

nature of the local interest involved, and on whether it could be promoted<br />

as well with a lesser impact on interstate activities. 0 2<br />

The main idea is that state regulation pursuing a legitimate interest is justified<br />

but should not be excessively burdensome on interstate commerce. This balancing<br />

test, in fact, leaves broad discretion to the courts to decide whether the burden on<br />

interstate commerce is excessive in relation to the benefits for the regulating state." 0 3<br />

Applying this judicial balancing test, the Supreme Court has "most often upheld the<br />

statute as one whose benefits outweigh its burdens." 2 °4 This reflects the fact that the<br />

ICC balancing test is less intrusive and more deferential towards regulatory decisionmaking<br />

than the ICC test as applied to discriminatory regulation.<br />

The application of this test goes beyond the ICC. Regulatory takings cases<br />

have developed over time using a variety of similar tests. The Rehnquist Court<br />

advanced a reasonable relationship test, which bore a striking similarity to the<br />

rational basis test utilized in economic analysis for Due Process and Equal<br />

Protection Clause cases. 05 The court also referred to this relationship as an essential<br />

nexus. 2°6 In Dolan v. City of Tigard, Chief Justice Rehnquist stated that despite any<br />

semantic differences, jurisdictions applied the proper reasonable relationship test,<br />

197. C & A Carbone v. Town of Clarkstown, 511 U.S. 383,392-93 (1994) (emphasis added).<br />

198. BARRON & DIENES, supra note 193, at 110-13.<br />

199. Id.<br />

200. Id. at 115.<br />

201. Id. at 114.<br />

202. Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 397 U.S. 137, 142 (1970) (citation omitted).<br />

203. ERWIN CHEMERINSKY, CONSTITUTIONAL LAW: PRINCIPLES AND POLICIES § 5.3.5 (2d ed. 2002).<br />

204. TRIBE, supra note 184, at 1062.<br />

205. Daniel A. Crane, A Poor Relation? Regulatory Takings after Dolan v. City of Tigard, 63 U. CHI.<br />

L. REV. 199,215 (1996).<br />

206. Nollan v. California Coastal Comm'n, 483 U.S. 825,837 (1987).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 406 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

balancing the state interest against the exaction of private property. Each is<br />

arguably a form of proportionality, the same which is applied in Eighth Amendment<br />

capital punishment cases, in the ICC and in every clash of congressional legislation<br />

with the interests<br />

8<br />

of the states .<br />

The Court's approach towards the Commerce Clause, and in particular the<br />

balancing test, has been subject to considerable criticism by judges and academics<br />

alike. 2 ' On the one hand, some are concerned that it is inappropriate for judges to<br />

engage in a balancing process of competing (and often non-comparable) values or<br />

interests, in particular with respect to non-discriminatory measures. It is argued that<br />

this should be left to the legislative process rather than to judicial activism. As a<br />

consequence, courts are considered to be ill-suited to undertake that kind of<br />

balancing. They should adopt a deferential approach instead of second-guessing<br />

regulatory measures." ° Another argument is that the balancing test has proven too<br />

uncertain and imprecise, which is why it has failed to become a guiding principle of<br />

constitutional law. This far-reaching debate on the merits of the Court's<br />

jurisprudence is beyond the scope of this article.<br />

A few conclusions can be drawn from the preceding discussion. First, both the<br />

least-restrictive means test and the balancing test provide standards against which<br />

regulatory measures can be assessed. This is a useful attempt to rationalize judicial<br />

review. Doubts remain as to whether the standards are sufficiently precise,<br />

intellectually coherent, and clear enough to provide guidance to the regulators, as<br />

well as to make judicial review more predictable. " ' The discussion about the<br />

Commerce Clause reflects similar issues arising in WTO law. It relates to the<br />

appropriate role for judges and judicial review in a federal and international legal<br />

system. It is also about the allocation of powers and the question of whose view<br />

should ultimately prevail in case of disputes: the judges' or the regulators' view.<br />

Both in the context of the Commerce Clause and WTO law, political<br />

representation arguments have been raised. One justification for judicial review is to<br />

ensure the appropriate protection of minorities (or foreigners) not represented in<br />

the domestic political process. These arguments can be turned into an important<br />

proceduralist aspect of substantive tests, such as balancing under the Commerce<br />

Clause or proportionality. The greater the representation of all interests affected in<br />

the domestic process, the more deference tribunals may show towards the political<br />

212<br />

process.<br />

207. Crane, supra note 205, at 223.<br />

208. Regarding the Eighth Amendment, see Ewing v. California, 538 U.S. 11 (2003). Regarding issues<br />

of federalism, see Tennessee v. Lane, 541 U.S. 509 (2004); F.E.R.C. v. Mississippi, 456 U.S. 742 (1982): U.S.<br />

v. Lopez, 514 U.S. 549 (1995).<br />

209. See, e.g., TRIBE, supra note 184.<br />

210. The Commerce Clause jurisprudence is a highly complex and difficult area of constitutional law.<br />

One commentator noted that "[glenerations of law students, judges, practicing lawyers, and legal<br />

commentators have struggled to understand exactly what the Supreme Court does when it decides cases<br />

involving the Dormant Commerce Clause." <strong>Law</strong>rence, supra note 184, at 464.<br />

211. <strong>Law</strong>rence, supra note 184, at 397.<br />

212. See Zleptnig, supra note 129, at 450-54: Robert Howse, Adjudicative Legitimacy and Treaty<br />

Interpretation in International Trade <strong>Law</strong>: The Early Years of WTO Jurisprudence, in THE EU, THE WTO<br />

AND THE NAFTA. TOWARDS A COMMON LAW OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE 35-69 (JHH Weiler, ed.,<br />

2000).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 407 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

VI. BALANCING IN THE WTO<br />

One aim of this paper is to outline some important areas of WTO law where<br />

proportionality or similar balancing tests do occur. The preceding discussion has<br />

shown that the concept of proportionality, while its core remains the same, has<br />

different constitutive elements and objectives which very much depends on the area<br />

of application of this principle. Another factor is that the different elements of the<br />

proportionality test may be applied with an ascending degree of scrutiny.<br />

Within WTO law, we can conceptually distinguish between two different areas<br />

of application: public policy exceptions, which limit the scope of legal rules and<br />

provide for derogations from main treaty obligations (e.g., GATT Article XX), and<br />

positive obligations imposed on Members by the SPS and TBT Agreements. These<br />

positive obligations lay down substantive criteria for domestic regulation to ensure<br />

that domestic regulation does not impose too burdensome constraints on<br />

international trade. 2 3<br />

Within either of these categories, one may further distinguish between the<br />

substantive and procedural aspects of the different tests. The substantive aspects lay<br />

down normative requirements to assess the compliance of domestic measures with<br />

WTO law. Related to substantive obligations are procedural obligations incumbent<br />

on the Members, which we will refer to as the procedural aspect. Procedural<br />

obligations need to be taken into account at the national level (in administrative<br />

proceedings or the legislative process) and will subsequently be reviewed by the<br />

judicial bodies of the WTO. Insofar as these procedural requirements relate to the<br />

quality of the domestic processes, they impose "procedural checks" on domestic<br />

decisionmaking 14<br />

A few authors have argued that the principle of proportionality is not explicitly<br />

(or even implicitly) recognized in the law of the WTO. 21 Our own approach in this<br />

chapter is to move the existing debate further and to outline some structural features<br />

inherent in the different tests laid down in the WTO Agreements. Whenever<br />

appropriate, we will draw parallels to the proportionality and balancing tests in other<br />

legal orders.<br />

A. Objective Justifications: Public Policy Exceptions in the GA TT<br />

1. Introduction<br />

GATT Article XX provides for a list of general exceptions from the GATT<br />

obligations. The scope and application of this provision is crucial for WTO Members<br />

that want to justify their domestic policies as GATT-consistent and invoke one of<br />

the public policy exceptions in Article XX. To date, this provision has already<br />

touched upon some of the most sensitive issues of WTO law and is likely in the<br />

future "to raise some of the most difficult questions that the WTO will face. 21 6<br />

213. Howse, supra note 188, at 154.<br />

214. Scott, supra note 123, at 337.<br />

215. See Desmedt supra note 3.<br />

216. Donald McRae, GATT Article XX and the WTO Appellate Body, in NEW DIRECTION IN<br />

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC LAW: ESSAYS IN HONOUR OF JOHN H. JACKSON 219, 233 (Marco Bronckers<br />

& Reinhard Quick eds., 2000).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 408 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

Any domestic measure, in order to qualify as a lawful exception under Art XX<br />

GATT, needs to comply with the conditions laid down in this provision. 2 7 The AB<br />

in US - Gasoline set out the appropriate method and sequence of steps for applying<br />

Article XX. 2 " This consists of two different steps, which, taken together, make the<br />

full assessment of a measure under Article XX. The first step is to assess whether<br />

the general design of a measure falls within the scope of one of the exceptions in<br />

Article XX (a) - (j). Subsequently, the application of a measure is assessed against<br />

the criteria in the introductory clauses (Chapeau) of Article XX.<br />

2. General Design<br />

The first step is to determine whether the domestic measure can be justified in<br />

accordance with one of the public policy exceptions. So far, the main focus of the<br />

case law has been on health measures (paragraph b), enforcement measures<br />

(paragraph d) and conservation measures (paragraph g). 2 9 The right of WTO<br />

Members to adopt a specific public policy objective and to choose the desired level<br />

of protection or enforcement has not been questioned by the panels or the AB. 22 ° In<br />

Asbestos, for instance, the AB held that "it is undisputed that WTO Members have<br />

the right to determine the level of protection of health that they consider<br />

appropriate in a given situation." 2 ' In US - Gasoline, the AB previously stated that<br />

"WTO Members were free to set their own environmental objectives, but they were<br />

bound to implement these objectives through measures consistent with ... [GATT]<br />

provisions.... ,,2 As far as the assessment of the appropriateness of the aim pursued<br />

is concerned, Members will have a wide margin of discretion. This discretion is<br />

subject to the condition that the chosen objective falls within the scope of the<br />

exceptions mentioned in Article XX GATT.<br />

The next step will be to determine the relationship, or connection, between the<br />

aim pursued and the measure adopted. This is a sensitive issue, for it has an impact<br />

on the intensity with which judges review (second-guess) domestic policy choices.<br />

The relationship between the aim and measure is typically at the core of any<br />

217. In this paper we will not specifically deal with Article XIV of the CATS, as it is equivalent to<br />

Art. XX GAIT; the recent U.S. - Gambling dispute confirmed that jurisprudence developed under Article<br />

XX of the GATT is also relevant for the interpretation of Article XIV of the GATS. For a discussion of<br />

the relevant GATS issues, see THE WORLD TRADE ORGANISATION AND TRADE IN SERVICES (Mads<br />

Andenas and Kern Alexander eds., 2007) and Panagiotis Delimatsis, Determining the Necessity of Domestic<br />

Regulations in Services. The Best is Yet to Come. 18 EUR. J. INT'L L (forthcoming, 2007) (arguing for a<br />

horizontal approach for all services sectors built on a necessity test to be adopted in the negotiations within<br />

the Working Part on Domestic Regulation based on the mandate in Art. VI:4 GATS).<br />

218. Panel Report, United <strong>State</strong>s - Standards for Reformulated and Conventional Gasoline, para. 6.20,<br />

WT/DS2/R (Jan. 29, 1996) [hereinafter U.S. - Gasoline PR], available at<br />

http://docsonline.wto.org/gen-search.asp?searchmode=simple (search by "document symbol").<br />

219. Committee on Trade and Environment, Note by the Secretariat: GATT/WTO Dispute Settlement<br />

Practice Relating to GA TT Article XX, Paragraphs (b), (d) and (g), WT/CTE/W/203 (March 8, 2002) at<br />

paras. 1-5 [hereinafter GA TT Secretariat].<br />

220. Id. para. 16.<br />

221. Appellate Body Report, Measures Affecting Asbestos and Asbestos-Containing Products, para.<br />

168. WT/DSI35/AB/R (Mar. 12, 2001) [hereinafter EC - Asbestos], available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/english/tratop-e/dispu-e/135abr-e.pdf.<br />

222. US - Gasoline, supra note 218, para. 7.1.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 409 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

proportionality inquiry (both in the domestic and international context) but also of<br />

other tests such as the Interstate Commerce Clause.<br />

In Article XX there is a textual difference in the individual paragraphs between<br />

the requirement that a measure be "necessary" to protect a specific public policy<br />

objective (e.g. public morals; human, animal or plant life or health) or, alternatively,<br />

that it be "related" to such an objective (conservation of exhaustible natural<br />

resources; products of prison labor). We now explore the scope and application of<br />

these two tests.<br />

i. Necessary to ...<br />

The necessity test in Articles XX (b) and (d) has been subject to considerable<br />

academic interest and also featured prominently in the WTO jurisprudence. In the<br />

Thai - Cigarettes case, the panel elaborated on the necessity criterion and stated that<br />

trade restrictions were necessary "only if there were no alternative measures<br />

consistent with the [GATT], or less inconsistent with it, which Thailand could<br />

reasonably be expected to employ to achieve its health policy objectives." 223 ' In US -<br />

Gasoline, the panel's standard was whether "there were measures consistent or less<br />

inconsistent with the General Agreement that were reasonably available ... ,224<br />

The focus on the least trade-restrictive and least GATT-inconsistent measure has led<br />

to considerable criticism in the academic literature, particularly for imposing too<br />

many constraints on legitimate domestic policy choices.<br />

Subsequent reports by the AB refined the necessity test. Korea - Beef is<br />

particularly relevant in this respect. According to the AB, in order to evaluate the<br />

necessity of a measure one needs to take into account, first, "the extent to which the<br />

measure contributes to the realization of the end pursued," and second, "the extent<br />

to which the compliance measure produces restrictive effects on international<br />

commerce." 225 ' As a consequence, measures with a lesser impact on international<br />

commerce "might more easily be considered as 'necessary' than a measure with<br />

intense or broader restrictive effects. 226 Summarizing its approach, the AB held that<br />

determination of whether a measure, which is not "indispensable", may<br />

nevertheless be "necessary" within the contemplation of Article XX(d),<br />

involves in every case a process of weighing and balancing a series of<br />

factors which prominently include the contribution made by the<br />

compliance measure to the enforcement of the law or regulation at issue,<br />

the importance of the common interests or values protected by that law<br />

or regulation, and the accompanying impact of the law or regulation on<br />

221<br />

imports or exports.<br />

The AB stressed that a "weighing and balancing" approach contributes to<br />

determining whether a Member could "reasonably be expected to employ" an<br />

223. Panel Report, Thailand - Restrictions on Importation of and Internal Taxes on Cigarettes, para.<br />

75, DSIO/R - 37S/200 (November 7, 1990) [hereinafter Thai - Cigarettes].<br />

224. US - Gasoline PR, supra note 218, para. 6.25.<br />

225. Appellate Body Report, Korea - Measures Affecting Imports of Fresh, Chilled and Frozen Beef,<br />

para. 163, VT/DS161/AB/R (Dec. 11, 2000) [hereinafter Korea - Beef], available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/english/tratop-e/dispu-e/161-169abr-e.pdf.<br />

226. Id.<br />

227. Id. para. 164.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 410 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

alternative measure or "whether a less WTO-inconsistent measure is reasonably<br />

available.<br />

' 228<br />

One interpretation of this judicial development is that the necessity test evolved<br />

from a "least-trade restrictive approach to a less-trade restrictive one, supplemented<br />

with a proportionality test ('a process of weighing and balancing of a series of<br />

factors'). '2 9 Within this balancing test, the AB will assess the relative importance of<br />

domestic interests or values pursued. This approach implies a significant shift<br />

towards a greater role of the panels and the AB in evaluating the legitimacy and<br />

necessity of domestic measures. On the other hand, some have argued that the<br />

approach in Korea - Beef introduces a more relaxed necessity test-a kind of de<br />

minimis rule-which leaves more discretion and an additional margin of<br />

appreciation to the Members. 3<br />

The AB further elaborated on the necessity requirement of Article XX in the<br />

Asbestos case. The report concludes that "in determining whether a suggested<br />

alternative measure is 'reasonably available,' several factors must be taken into<br />

account, besides the difficulty of implementation., 23 ' That determination will be<br />

influenced by the "the weighing and balancing" of various factors, as outlined in<br />

Korea - Beef. 32 The main factors that need to be taken into account in this<br />

assessment are (a) the extent to which the alternative measure contributes to the<br />

realization of the end pursued and (b) the importance of the interests and values<br />

pursued by the Member. 3 It is then necessary to assess whether there "is an<br />

alternative measure that would achieve the same end and that is less restrictive of<br />

trade than a prohibition." 234 ' This approach does not put into question the objective<br />

pursued by the Member, but is intended to provide a standard for evaluating the<br />

necessity of a domestic measure.<br />

In recent disputes the AB has confirmed and applied the concept of necessity as<br />

previously developed in Korea - Beef and EC - Asbestos. The AB report in US -<br />

Gambling elaborated on the necessity standard under Art XIV(a) GATS, and the<br />

AB report in Dominican Republic- Cigarettes dealt with the necessity standard<br />

under Art XX(d) GATT .<br />

228. Id. para. 166.<br />

229. GA TT Secretariat, supra note 219, para. 42.<br />

230. Neumann & Ttrk, supra note 5, at 211: Robert Howse & Elisabeth Turk, The WTO Impact on<br />

Internal Regulations-A Case Study of the Canada - EC Asbestos Dispute, in THE EU AND THE WTO.<br />

LEGAL AND CONSTITUTIONAL ISSUES 283, 324-25 (Griinne de B(Irca & Joanne Scott eds., 2001). See also<br />

Panagiotis Delimatsis Determining the Necessity of Domestic Regulations in Services. The Best is Yet to<br />

Come 18 EUR. J. INT'L L (forthcoming, 2007)(going further in finding a shift that allows for a less intrusive<br />

necessity test with greater regulatory diversity, and supporting this on his analysis of Dominican Republic -<br />

Cigarettes, infra note 244).<br />

231. EC- Asbestos, supra note 221, para. 170.<br />

232. Korea - Beef, supra note 225, para. 164.<br />

233. For instance, the more important the interest or value pursued, the easier it will be to justify the<br />

domestic measure enacted to achieve that objective as "necessary." See Korea - Beef, supra note 225<br />

paras. 163-164.<br />

234. EC- Asbestos, supra note 221, para. 172.<br />

235. Appellate Body Report, United <strong>State</strong>s - Measures Affecting the Cross-Border Supply of<br />

Gambling and Betting Services, paras. 304-327, WT/DS285/AB/R (Apr. 7. 2005) [hereinafter US -<br />

Gambling], available at http:/www.wto.org/englishltratop-e/dispu-e/285arb13-e.pdf: Appellate Body<br />

Report, Dominican Republic - Measures Affecting the Importation and Internal Sale of Cigarettes paras.<br />

57-74, WT/DS302/AB/R (Apr. 25, 2005) [hereinafter Dominican Republic - Cigarettes], available at<br />

http://www.wto.orglEnglish/tratop-e/dispu-e/302abr-e.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 411 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

In sum, the necessity test seems to imply the following: a measure is necessary if<br />

it is indispensable or alternative measures are not reasonably available to achieve<br />

the same legitimate public policy objective. 236 This determination will be made upon<br />

a weighing and balancing of different factors, including the trade-restrictive effects<br />

of the measure, the importance of the aim pursued, and the contribution made by<br />

possible alternative measures to achieve that aim pursued. This test certainly<br />

introduces a flexible balancing approach into Article XX GATT and a certain<br />

degree of subjectivity on the part of the judiciary. At the same time, it requires both<br />

the judiciary and the parties to the dispute to structure and justify their arguments<br />

along the lines defined by the AB in its jurisprudence and to present the arguments<br />

in such a way that they fit with the requirements imposed by the necessity analysis.<br />

ii.<br />

Relating to...<br />

Other exceptions in Article XX are subject to the condition that the measure is<br />

"related to" a legitimate public policy objective (e.g. conservation of exhaustible<br />

natural resources in Article XX(g)). The term "related to" indicates that this<br />

standard requires a looser degree of connection between the measure and the aim<br />

than the stricter necessity test. The AB in Korea - Beef stressed that the term<br />

"relating to" is "more flexible textually than the 'necessity requirement' found in<br />

Article XX(d)." 237 ' Initially, the GATT panel in the Canada - Salmon and Herring<br />

case argued that "relating to" included not only measures that are necessary or<br />

essential to achieve the conservation of exhaustible natural resources but are<br />

"primarily aimed at" the chosen objective."" Subsequently, the AB in US - Gasoline<br />

clarified that the term "relating to" requires at least a "substantial relationship"<br />

between the means and end which "cannot be regarded as merely incidentally or<br />

inadvertently aimed at the conservation of clean air ....<br />

In US - Shrimp, the AB assessed whether the domestic measure was<br />

"reasonably related" to the ends, arguing that "[t]he means and ends relationship<br />

[between the measure and the policy pursued in that case] ... is observably a close<br />

and real one . ,240 This was also the AB's interpretation of the test as applied in<br />

the previous Gasoline case. The AB reaffirmed that the requirement of "relating to"<br />

is about a "close and genuine relationship of end and means. 24 ' The AB further<br />

held that the design of the domestic measure was "not disproportionately wide in its<br />

236. In Korea - Beef, the AB referred to "a range of degrees of necessity," and determined that<br />

indispensable, absolutely necessary and inevitable measures "certainly fulfill the requirements of Article<br />

XX (d)." Korea - Beef, supra note 225, para. 161.<br />

237. Id. para. 161, n. 104.<br />

238. Panel Report, Canada - Measures Affecting Exports of Unprocessed Herring and Salmon, para.<br />

4.6, L/6286 - 35S/98 (Nov. 20, 1987) [hereinafter Canada - Herring], available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/gatt-docs/English/SULPDF/91330016.pdf.<br />

239. Appellate Body Report, United <strong>State</strong>s - Standards for Reformulated and Conventional Gasoline,<br />

19, WT/DS2/AB/R (Apr. 29, 1996) [hereinafter U.S. - Gasoline ABR], available at<br />

http://docsonline.wto.org/gen search.asp?searchmode=simple (search by "document symbol").<br />

240. Appellate Body Report, United <strong>State</strong>s - Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp<br />

Products, para. 141, WT/DS58/AB/R (Oct. 12, 1998) [hereinafter US - Shrimp], available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/English/tratop-e/dispu-e/58abr.pdf.<br />

241. Id. para. 136.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 412 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

scope and reach in relation to the policy objective of protection and conservation of<br />

sea turtle species." 2 '2<br />

While the scope of the "relating to" test is still somewhat unclear, the AB has at<br />

least outlined some general criteria for that test." 3 The main requirements are a<br />

"close and genuine relationship" between the measure and the aim pursued, which,<br />

in other words, need to be reasonably related. " The test is less strict than the<br />

necessity test. This may lead to the result that-insofar as the specific tests are<br />

concerned-a measure relating to environmental objectives can be justified more<br />

easily under Art XX(g) GAT (conservation of exhaustible natural resources) than<br />

under Article XX(b) GATT (protection of human, animal or plant life or health). In<br />

both cases, WTO Members can define and choose without judicial interference the<br />

level of protection they consider appropriate. The assessment of the measures<br />

adopted pursuant to that policy choice, however, will be more intrusive. First, the<br />

necessity test requires an assessment of whether a WTO Member could reasonably<br />

have been expected to employ a less trade-restrictive alternative. This<br />

determination will be governed by a balancing and weighing of different factors.<br />

Conversely, the "related to" test seems to be a more deferential reasonableness<br />

standard which also includes some elements of a proportionality inquiry. 24<br />

3. Application of the Measure: The Chapeau<br />

In the preceding analyses we focused on the tests set out in individual<br />

paragraphs of Article XX GATT. If a national measure is found to comply with<br />

these requirements, it will be "provisionally justified. 2 1 6 The next step is to turn to<br />

the introductory clause of Article XX GATT, also known as Chapeau, to determine<br />

whether a measure, in its concrete application, is lawful under Article XX as a whole.<br />

The chapeau reads as follows:<br />

Subject to the requirement that such measures are not applied in a manner<br />

which would constitute a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination<br />

between countries where the same conditions prevail, or a disguised<br />

restriction on international trade, nothing in this Agreement shall be<br />

construed to prevent the adoption or enforcement by any contracting<br />

party of measures .... 247<br />

In US - Gasoline the AB had begun to develop a coherent theory regarding<br />

both the function of the chapeau and its relationship with the general exceptions.<br />

The AB stressed that the "purpose and object of the introductory clauses of Article<br />

XX is generally the prevention of [abuse of the exceptions in Article XX]." 2 8 While<br />

those exceptions "may be invoked as a matter of legal right, they should not be<br />

242. Id. para. 141.<br />

243. McRae, supra note 216, at 226.<br />

244. Id.<br />

245. Desmedt, supra note 4, at 470-76.<br />

246. US - Shrimp, supra note 240, para. 147.<br />

247. General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, art. XX chapeau, Oct 30, 1994, 1867 U.N.T.S. 187<br />

(emphasis added) [hereinafter GATT].<br />

248. U.S. - Gasoline ABR, supra note 239, at 22.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 413 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

applied so as to frustrate or defeat the legal obligations of the holder of the right<br />

under the substantive rules of the [GATT]. '24 9<br />

The main idea that the chapeau shall prevent an abuse of the right to invoke an<br />

exception by a Member was refined in US - Shrimp. Here the AB stated that the<br />

Chapeau "embodies the recognition on the part of the WTO Members of the need<br />

to maintain a balance of rights and obligations between the right of a Member to<br />

invoke one or another of the exceptions of Article XX ... on the one hand, and the<br />

substantive rights of the other Members under the GAT" 1994, on the other<br />

hand." 25 The AB further noted: "[t]he same concept may be expressed from a<br />

slightly different angle of vision. Thus, a balance must be struck between the right of<br />

a Member to invoke an exception under Article XX and the duty of that same<br />

Member to respect the treaty rights of other Members." '<br />

Interestingly, the AB focuses on the balancing of competing rights, interests<br />

and obligations as the predominant feature within the chapeau analysis. This<br />

expresses the concern of the AB to prevent abuse of the general exceptions which<br />

are only available upon a careful balancing of different factors.<br />

The wording of the chapeau provides for three different standards for domestic<br />

measures.2 52 These must neither constitute "arbitrary discrimination" or<br />

"unjustifiable discrimination" between countries where the same conditions prevail,<br />

nor must they constitute "a disguised restriction on international trade. 2 53 US -<br />

Shrimp demonstrates that the interpretation and application of these three<br />

requirements will be influenced and governed by the overarching balancing<br />

approach . 4<br />

With regard to the test of "arbitrary discrimination," the AB held that the<br />

certification proceedings adopted in the United <strong>State</strong>s:<br />

appear to be singularly informal and casual, and to be conducted in a<br />

manner such that these processes could result in the negation of rights of<br />

Members. . . . It appears to us that, effectively, exporting Members<br />

applying for certificates whose applications are rejected are denied basic<br />

fairness and due process, and are discriminated against, vis-A-vis those<br />

Members which are granted certification. 255<br />

The requirements in the chapeau indicate that Members wanting to invoke an<br />

exception to Article XX need to apply their measures in a reasonable manner,<br />

taking into account not only their own treaty rights but also those of other GATT<br />

Members. It is this balancing process which will ultimately determine whether a<br />

discriminatory measure is arbitrary or unjustifiable, or constitutes a disguised<br />

restriction on international trade.<br />

Balancing does not necessarily involve such broad and general objectives as<br />

free trade and environmental protection. The way in which balancing has been<br />

developed in the jurisprudence of the AB implies a weighing of more concrete rights<br />

249. Id.<br />

250. US- Shrimp, supra note 240, para. 156.<br />

251. Id.<br />

252. Id. para. 150.<br />

253. Id.<br />

254. See McRae, supra note 216, at 229-33.<br />

255. US - Shrimp, supra note 240, para. 181.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 414 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

and interests at stake. This process resembles a proportionality analysis.<br />

Historically and conceptually, proportionality is very much about the balancing of<br />

one or more public policy objectives against concrete individual or collective rights<br />

and interests. One could argue that this is also one of the AB's interpretations of the<br />

chapeau. Such an approach does not question the general policy objective pursued<br />

by the Members, but it introduces a test to assess whether a concrete measure, as<br />

applied, is disproportionate or unreasonable.<br />

In US - Shrimp, the AB found that a measure constituted unjustifiable and<br />

arbitrary discrimination since that discrimination could reasonably have been<br />

avoided. That aspect of the analysis, in particular the assessment whether<br />

discrimination is unjustifiable or arbitrary, requires a typical balancing of competing<br />

rights and interests protected by the GATT. Part of the assessment in US - Shrimp<br />

turned on factors inherent in the regulatory process, such as transparency, due<br />

process or elements of basic fairness in domestic administrative proceedings. 2 6 This<br />

can be seen as the procedural side of the balancing test or proportionality inquiry,<br />

recognizing that rights and interests can only be realized through fair and equitable<br />

domestic procedures. Such a proceduralist approach in the assessment of trade<br />

restrictions might lead to greater deference toward domestic regulatory choices<br />

although it includes, at the same time, a close scrutiny of the regulatory processes<br />

underlying the decision-making process."'<br />

3. Conclusion: How the Tests in Article XX GATT Operate<br />

One function of Article XX is to define the scope of the legal obligations under<br />

this provision."' This is done through a two-step analysis which includes different<br />

standards and tests necessity or reasonableness. It also involves the due balancing of<br />

the right of a WTO Member to invoke the exception and the substantive rights of<br />

other WTO Members.<br />

It has been argued that "in no case will the proportionality requirements<br />

contained in Article XX of GATT' allow for a 'balancing test' of advantages resulting<br />

from overall trade objectives underlying the WTO agreements with the advantages<br />

resulting from national policy objectives as mentioned in the individual clauses of<br />

Article XX." ' 9 Our approach is slightly different. One aspect of proportionality is<br />

to govern the scope and application of exceptions such as Article XX and, as a<br />

consequence, to evaluate and balance the different interests at stake. As outlined<br />

above, balancing within Article XX needs to be undertaken several times in order to<br />

determine the necessity, reasonableness or proportionality of a particular measure.<br />

The question in those cases is to determine which rights or interests need to be<br />

balanced against each other, and it would be misleading to reduce this balancing act<br />

solely to general trade versus non-trade concerns.<br />

Within the scope of Article XX, proportionality can be seen as a governing<br />

principle and flexible tool to guide the judicial inquiry into the lawfulness of<br />

domestic measures. In the chapter on proportionality in public international law, we<br />

256. ld. paras. 181-182: Scott, supra note 123, at 350-351.<br />

257. Scott, supra note 123, at 350-351.<br />

258. See McRae, supra note 216, at 232.<br />

259. Desmedt, supra note 4, at 476.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 415 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

concluded that proportionality is a standard to determine how far states can go in<br />

their relationship with other states. Very often such a proportionality inquiry will<br />

not only include quantitative elements but also a balancing of protected rights,<br />

interests and values. We are well aware that proportionality, for instance, in the law<br />

of international countermeasures has a different normative role to play. Yet it is<br />

interesting to note that the necessity and balancing approach developed by the AB<br />

in the application of Article XX GATT structurally resembles the proportionality<br />

analysis in other areas of international law.<br />

Finally, the balancing in Article XX should not be reduced to crude balancing<br />

of free trade against other legitimate public policy objectives, to the detriment of<br />

either of those categories. The test is more sophisticated than that, compared to the<br />

application of the principle of proportionality in EC law. Balancing in Article XX<br />

relates to (and influences) very specific legal requirements such as "necessary to,"<br />

"arbitrary," "unjustifiable" or "disguised." Those provisions are interpreted through<br />

a subtle balancing of the different interests at stake. Taken together, these different<br />

tests define the treatment of domestic measures under Article XX. This approach is<br />

more refined and structured than the proportionality analysis in Article 30 EC. It is<br />

also more structured than the US Interstate Commerce Clause or the general<br />

application of the principle of proportionality in public international law.<br />

B. Positive Obligations for Domestic Regulation<br />

The SPS Agreement and the TBTAgreement set out detailed positive<br />

obligations for domestic regulation. The most prominent standards are necessity,<br />

reasonableness, and proportionality. They apply as independent, positive<br />

requirements for domestic regulation and not just as justification provisions for a<br />

prima facie violation of other provisions. The positive obligations set out in the SPS<br />

and TBT Agreements are intended to mitigate the trade-restrictive effects of<br />

domestic regulation, while leaving sufficient discretion to Members to pursue their<br />

domestic public policy objectives.<br />

1. SPS Agreement<br />

The SPS Agreement applies to "all sanitary or phytosanitary measures which<br />

may, directly or indirectly, affect international trade. '' 26 0 One aim of the agreement is<br />

to provide national authorities with appropriate and clear normative standards to<br />

find a balance between trade liberalization and national regulatory competences. 2 6 '<br />

The Preamble to the SPS Agreement mentions, among others, two major concerns:<br />

1) that domestic sanitary and phytosanitary measures shall constitute neither<br />

arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination between WTO Members nor a disguised<br />

restriction on international trade and 2) that the multilateral framework governing<br />

sanitary and phytosanitary measures contributes to minimizing their negative effects<br />

on international trade .<br />

260. Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures, Art. 1, Apr. 15, 1994,<br />

Multilateral Agreement on Trade in Goods, Annex 1 [hereinafter SPS], available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/english/docs-e/legal-e/15-sps.pdf.<br />

261. ORTINO, supra note 100, at 457.<br />

262. SPS, supra note 260, Preamble.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 416 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

SPS measures are a very sensitive area of WTO law and policy. They often<br />

significantly impact core areas of public policy, such as national health and safety.<br />

According to the SPS Agreement, each WTO Member is free to determine its own<br />

appropriate level of sanitary or phytosanitary protection. 26 The determination of the<br />

appropriate level of protection is considered by the AB to be "a prerogative of the<br />

Member concerned and not of the panel or of the Appellate Body. '2 M The chosen<br />

level of protection is generally not questioned by the panels, and WTO Members<br />

could well pursue a zero-risk approach (if it complies with the other conditions of the<br />

SPS Agreement). However, the instrument chosen to attain that level of protection<br />

will be assessed as to whether it is adequate and complies with the necessity<br />

requirements laid down in the SPS Agreement. Within the scope of the SPS<br />

Agreement it is important to outline this distinction between the objective pursued<br />

by the state and the instrument chosen to attain that objective. 65<br />

Article 5.4 of the SPS Agreement requires Members, in determining their level<br />

of protection, to "take into account the objective of minimizing negative trade<br />

effects. 2 6 1 This provision could been seen as allowing for a full balancing of<br />

competing objectives, along the lines of proportionality stricto sensu (i.e., no<br />

excessive impact on trade). Yet the more limited nature and legal effect of this<br />

provision was clearly outlined by the panel in the Hormones case:<br />

Guided by the wording of Article 5.4, in particular the words "should"<br />

(not "shall") and "objective", we consider that this provision of the SPS<br />

Agreement does not impose an obligation. However, this objective of<br />

minimizing negative trade effects has nonetheless to be taken into account<br />

'<br />

in the interpretation of other provisions of the SPS Agreement.<br />

One possible reading of Article 5.4 of the SPS Agreement is that Members<br />

should avoid measures with excessive trade-restrictive effects. This means that the<br />

determination of the appropriate level of protection by a Member is subject to the<br />

condition that it "should" take into account the effects on trade.1 6 Due to this<br />

wording, Article 5.4 does not seem to allow for a true balancing and trade-off of<br />

possible negative effects on trade against the desired level of protection. It does not<br />

require any cost-benefit analysis of the intended level of protection either. These<br />

restrictions would run counter to the AB's repeated findings that it is the Member's<br />

prerogative to determine the appropriate level of protection.<br />

Panels may face the difficulty that Members do not determine their appropriate<br />

level of protection explicitly or with sufficient precision. The AB stated that, in such<br />

circumstances, panels may establish the Member's level of protection on the basis of<br />

the actual SPS measure applied. 269 Such an initial determination is necessary to<br />

263. Id. art. 2.<br />

264. Appellate Body Report, Australia - Measures Affecting Importation of Salmon, para. 199,<br />

WT/DS18/AB/R (November 6,1998) [hereinafter Australia - Salmon] (emphasis omitted), available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/English/tratop-e/dispu-e/dsl 8abr.pdf.<br />

265. Id. para. 200.<br />

266. SPS, supra note 260, art. 5.4.<br />

267. Panel Report, European Communities - Measures Affecting Meat and Meat Products, para. 8.166.,<br />

WT/DS26/R (August 18, 1997) [hereinafter EC- Hormones PR].<br />

268. SPS, supra note 260, art. 5.4.<br />

269. Japan - Apples, supra note 147, para. 207.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 417 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

assess whether the measure adopted complies with the relevant provisions of the<br />

SPS Agreement.<br />

Subsequently, WTO Members need to undertake a risk assessment, upon which<br />

the national measures shall be based. 270 The AB has clarified that the criterion that<br />

the measure be "based on" risk assessment requires "a rational relationship between<br />

the measure and the risk assessment. '7 ' In other words, Members can only lawfully<br />

enact a SPS measure in those cases where the risk assessment "reasonably<br />

support[s]" the measure at stake. Note that the rational relationship requirement<br />

is a separate obligation from the traditional necessity or proportionality analysis in<br />

other provisions of the SPS Agreement.<br />

According to Article 2.2 of the SPS Agreement, domestic measures cannot not<br />

be maintained without "sufficient scientific evidence., 273 Clarifying this provision,<br />

the AB in Japan - Apples followed the panel's conclusions and held that the<br />

sufficient scientific evidence criterion requires a "'rational and objective relationship'<br />

between the measure and the relevant scientific evidence., 274 The panel in this case,<br />

noting the lack of sufficient scientific evidence to support the Japanese measure, had<br />

found that the measure at issue was "clearly disproportionate to the risk identified on<br />

the basis of the scientific evidence available. 279<br />

The next step of analysis is to turn to the necessity of the measure. This relates<br />

to the relationship between the aim pursued and the measure at issue. Article 2.2 of<br />

the SPS Agreement requires that any SPS measure is "applied only to the extent<br />

necessary to protect human, animal or plant life or health ... ,,276 Article 5.6 of the<br />

SPS Agreement refines this obligation, requiring WTO Members to ensure that SPS<br />

measures are not "more trade-restrictive than required to achieve their appropriate<br />

level of . . . protection, taking into account technical and economic feasibility., 277<br />

Footnote 3, which is attached to Article 5.6 of the SPS Agreement, further delineates<br />

the concept of necessity:<br />

[A] measure is not more trade-restrictive than required unless there is<br />

another measure, reasonably available taking into account technical and<br />

economic feasibility, that achieves the appropriate level of sanitary or<br />

phytosanitary protection and is significantly less restrictive to trade. 278<br />

The AB in Australia - Salmon elaborated on the necessity test and mainly<br />

referred to the requirements grounded in Footnote 3 of the SPS Agreement. It held<br />

that the three elements are cumulative, in the sense that all three elements have to<br />

be met for a finding of inconsistency with Article 5.6 of the SPS Agreement. 279 A<br />

measure will therefore be consistent with Article 5.6 of the SPS Agreement if there<br />

270. See SPS, supra note 260, arts. 2.2, 5.1.<br />

271. EC- Hormones ABR. supra note 119, para. 193 (emphasis added).<br />

272. Id.<br />

273. SPS, supra note 260, art. 2.2 (emphasis added).<br />

274. Japan - Apples, supra note 147, para. 147.<br />

275. Id. para. 163 (emphasis added).<br />

276. SPS, supra note 260, art. 2.2 (emphasis added).<br />

277. Id. art. 5.6.<br />

278. Id. at n.3.<br />

279. Australia - Salmon, supra note 264, para. 194.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 418 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

is no alternative measure available, if the alternative measure does not achieve the<br />

appropriate level of protection, or if it is not significantly less trade-restrictive.""<br />

Some have argued that the components of the necessity test as outlined above<br />

(in particular, the criteria of being reasonably available and significantly less<br />

restrictive to trade) indicate a relaxed necessity test under the SPS Agreement.<br />

Member states may choose among several alternatives without being obliged to opt<br />

for the least trade-restrictive measure. This approach resembles the necessity<br />

requirement under Article XX GATT for which the AB introduced a flexible<br />

balancing approach. The conceptual similarity between Article XX GATT and<br />

Article 5.6 of the SPS Agreement remains to open to future clarification. With<br />

regard to the burden of proof, the complainant must establish a prima facie case that<br />

there exists an alternative measure which meets all three requirements, i.e. establish<br />

the prima facie inconsistency of the national measure with the SPS Agreement.<br />

Member states are further required to comply with an additional discipline laid<br />

down in Article 5.5 of the SPS Agreement. The relevant part of this provision reads<br />

as follows:<br />

With the objective of achieving consistency in the application of the<br />

concept of appropriate level of sanitary or phytosanitary protection<br />

against risks to human life or health, or to animal and plant life or health,<br />

each Member shall avoid arbitrary or unjustifiable distinctions in the levels<br />

it considers to be appropriate in different situations, if such distinctions<br />

result in discrimination or a disguised restriction on international trade. 28 '<br />

The objective of this provision, which needs to be read in the context of Article<br />

2.3 of the SPS Agreement, is to achieve "consistency in the application of the<br />

concept of appropriate level of ... protection" within the state. 283 The underlying<br />

rationale is to prevent products that are similarly dangerous from being given<br />

different treatment: for instance, through a very high level of protection in one case<br />

and a very lenient treatment in another.' The AB in EC - Hormones and Australia<br />

- Salmon specified the three elements which are part of the test under Article 5.5<br />

SPS. First, the WTO Member adopts different appropriate levels of protection in<br />

different situations. Second, the different levels of protection are arbitrary or<br />

unjustifiable. Finally, the arbitrary or unjustifiable distinctions in the level of<br />

protection result in either discrimination or a disguised restriction of international<br />

trade.2"<br />

280. Id.<br />

281. SPS, supra note 260, art. 5.5.<br />

282. Article 2.3 SPS reads as follows: "Members shall ensure that their sanitary and phytosanitary<br />

measures do not arbitrarily or unjustifiably discriminate between Members where identical or similar<br />

conditions prevail, including between their own territory and that of other Members. Sanitary and<br />

phytosanitary measures shall not be applied in a manner which would constitute a disguised restriction on<br />

international trade." SPS, supra note 260, art. 2.3.<br />

283. Id.<br />

284. Joost Pauwelyn, The WTO Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary (SPS) Measures as Applied<br />

in the First Three SPS Disputes: EC - Hormones, Australia - Salmon, Japan - Varietals, 2 J. INT'L ECON. L.<br />

641,653 (1999).<br />

285. EC- Hormones ABR, supra note 119, para. 214.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 419 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

The third element ("discrimination" or "disguised restriction") seems<br />

conceptually the most controversial.8 The AB in EC - Hormones ruled that<br />

arbitrary or unjustifiable differences in the levels of protection may act as a "warning<br />

signal" that the measure in its application leads to discrimination between Members<br />

or to a disguised restriction on international trade. 287 What therefore needs to be<br />

proven to find a violation of the third element of Article 5.5 SPS is that the Member<br />

in fact applies the SPS measure in a way which either discriminates between WTO<br />

Members or constitutes a disguised restriction, i.e., it provides protection for the<br />

domestic producers. In the subsequent Australia - Salmon case, the AB made an<br />

interesting finding concerning what constitutes a disguised restriction on<br />

international trade. It held that a measure that is not based on risk assessment<br />

strongly indicates a "trade-restrictive measure taken in the guise of an SPS measure,<br />

i.e., a 'disguised restriction on international trade'."""<br />

The wording of Article 5.5 is clearly modeled upon the chapeau of Article XX<br />

of the GATT. Despite this similarity, the AB ruled out that the interpretation and<br />

reasoning of the chapeau may be imported into the analysis of Article 5.5 of the SPS<br />

Agreement. The justification provided by the AB is that there are "structural<br />

differences" between those two provisions and the standards they impose. 8 9 The<br />

chapeau of Article XX GATT is generally more concerned with preventing the<br />

abuse of rights in the application of a measure, whereas Article 5.5 SPS primarily<br />

aims for consistency in the levels of protection with the aim to reduce unnecessary<br />

regulation. 290<br />

As was shown above, Article 5.5 does not require "absolute and perfect<br />

consistency" in the appropriate levels of protection in different situations. The AB<br />

recognizes that the different levels of protection are set on an "ad hoc basis and over<br />

time," whereby the perception of risks is not the same at all times. Arbitrary and<br />

unjustifiable inconsistencies, however, are prohibited under the SPS Agreement.<br />

The SPS Agreement attempts to bridge the gap between national regulatory<br />

autonomy and protectionist trade restrictions enacted as sanitary and phytosanitary<br />

measures. The individual provisions of the SPS Agreement guide the task of the<br />

panels and the AB to strike the delicate balance between necessary, legitimate, and<br />

protectionist measures. On the one hand, the agreement does not authorise a broad<br />

balancing of the costs and benefits of a regulatory measure in the sense of<br />

proportionality stricto sensu. Most importantly, Members are free to determine their<br />

level of protection without judicial interference, except for the requirement that<br />

differences in levels of protection shall be consistent. The Agreement's detailed<br />

provisions, however, provide strict normative standards for the instruments chosen<br />

and applied by a WTO Member to achieve its level of protection. The necessity<br />

requirement aims to ensure that the chosen measure is no more trade restrictive than<br />

necessary. Proportionality elements also govern the determination whether<br />

different levels of protection are reasonably consistent and do not result in<br />

discrimination or a disguised restriction on trade. As outlined above, this<br />

286. Pauwelyn, supra note 284, at 654.<br />

287. EC- Hormones ABR, supra note 119, para. 215.<br />

288. Australia - Salmon, supra note 264, para. 166.<br />

289. EC- Hormones ABR, supra note 119, para. 239.<br />

290. JAN NEUMANN, DIE KOORDINATION DES WTO-RECHTS MIT ANDEREN VOLKERRECHTLICHEN<br />

ORDNUNGEN. KONFLIKTE DES MATERIELLEN RECHTS UND KONKURRENZEN DER STREITBEILEGUNG<br />

479 (2002).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 420 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

consistency requirement is subject to different conditions whose normative content<br />

remains somewhat elusive. For instance, there is some leeway in determining which<br />

distinctions in the levels of protection will be considered arbitrary or unjustifiable<br />

and those that will be acceptable. A further question is how far the consistency<br />

requirement imposes constraints on WTO Members to autonomously determine<br />

their level of protection and whether this does not lead to a true balancing of<br />

competing factors (chosen level of protection vs. discrimination; trade restriction vs.<br />

arbitrariness and justifiability) by means of judicial review.<br />

2. TBT Agreement<br />

The Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT Agreement) aims to<br />

ensure, among other things, that national regulations, standards, testing, and<br />

certification procedures do not create unnecessary obstacles to international trade.<br />

Our analysis of the TBT Agreement primarily focuses on Article 2.2 as this provision<br />

seems most relevant for the purposes of this paper.<br />

Within the scope of the TBT Agreement, both the policy objectives pursued by<br />

the Member and the level at which it decides to pursue those obligations are<br />

prerogatives of the states. 29 ' The preamble of the TBT Agreement recognizes that<br />

no Member shall be prevented from determining its appropriate level of<br />

protection. 92 This is similar to the WTO Members' discretion identified under the<br />

SPS Agreement.<br />

The substantive obligation in Article 2.2 TBT requires that<br />

Members shall ensure that technical regulations are not prepared, adopted<br />

or applied with a view to or with the effect of creating unnecessary<br />

obstacles to international trade. For this purpose, technical regulations<br />

shall not be more trade-restrictive than necessary to fulfil a legitimate<br />

objective, taking account of the risks non-fulfilment would create. 293<br />

The last sentence refers to "legitimate objectives" that domestic measures (i.e.,<br />

"technical regulations") aim to achieve. Article 2.2 TBT defines those objectives in<br />

a non-exhaustive list. The objectives include, among others, national security<br />

requirements, the prevention of deceptive practices, and protection of the<br />

environment. Both the panel and the AB in EC - Sardines stated that this list is only<br />

illustrative; other objectives may also be considered "legitimate." It is for the<br />

Member to determine those objectives.<br />

While the chosen level of protection may not be called into question, the<br />

subsequent assessment of a domestic measure under Article 2.2 TBT takes place in<br />

different steps. Technical regulations must first be capable of contributing to a<br />

"legitimate objective." In contrast to the SPS Agreement, this term indicates that the<br />

291. Panel Report, European Communities - Trade Description of Sardines, para. 7.120, WT/DS231/R<br />

(May 29, 2002) [hereinafter EC - Sardines PR], available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/english/tratop-e/dispu-e/231r-e.pdf.<br />

292. Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade, Preamble, April 15, 1994, Multilateral Agreement on<br />

Trade in Goods, Annex 1 [hereinafter TBT].<br />

293. Id. art. 2.2 (emphasis added).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 421 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

object and purpose of a measure may be questioned by the panels with regard to<br />

their legitimacy. The AB in EC -Sardines clearly stated that it was prepared to<br />

examine and determine the legitimacy of a TBT measure's objective, and the panel<br />

equally ruled that it was required to do so. 294 Interestingly, the panel in EC -<br />

Sardines referred to a finding of the panel in Canada - Pharmaceuticals Patents,<br />

which defined the notion of "legitimate interests" in the context of Article 30 of the<br />

TRIPS Agreement. 2 95 The panel in Canada - Pharmaceutical Patents stated that a<br />

legitimate interest is "a normative claim calling for protection of interests that are<br />

'justifiable' in the sense that they are supported by relevant public policies or other<br />

social norms. 2 96<br />

Some authors are skeptical about the possibility that panels and the AB<br />

question the legitimacy of objectives pursued by WTO Members. Neumann and<br />

Tuirk, for instance, argued that Article 2.2 TBT should not equip WTO tribunals with<br />

the ability to a priori rule out the legitimacy of measures, since this could interfere<br />

with domestic policy choices. In addition to such political considerations, recital 6 of<br />

the TBT-Preamble clearly establishes that WTO Members remain free to adopt their<br />

level of protection. If the level of protection remains a national domaine r~serv , it is<br />

not evident that the decision which value is legitimate should be centralized at the<br />

WTO level. 297 We believe that there are also some valid arguments against this<br />

interpretation. Textually, Article 2.2 incorporates the notion of legitimate objectives,<br />

which implies that there are illegitimate objectives as well. The question then is<br />

"Who shall ultimately determine whether a measure is legitimate or illegitimate with<br />

regard to Article 2.2 TBT?" It would be unduly deferential towards WTO Members<br />

to let them decide on the legitimacy of the objectives pursued, without subjecting<br />

them to any subsequent oversight by the WTO judicial bodies. Finally, the issue of<br />

legitimate objectives should not necessarily be discussed together with the<br />

appropriate level of protection. As was stated by the Sardines panel, "it is up to the<br />

Members to decide which policy objectives they wish to pursue and the levels at<br />

which they wish to pursue them." '2 98 These two issues closely interrelate, but they<br />

should be assessed independently of each other.<br />

If a measure has a legitimate objective, it shall be no "more trade-restrictive<br />

than necessary." 2 99 It is one of the key objectives of the TBT Agreement that<br />

Members avoid unnecessary obstacles to international trade. This requirement<br />

imposes constraints on the WTO Members which are similar to the least traderestrictiveness<br />

requirement under the SPS Agreement. Referring to the preamble,<br />

294. Appellate Body Report, European Communities - Trade Description of Sardines, para. 286.,<br />

WT/DS231/AB/R (September 26, 2002) [hereinafter EC - Sardines ABR], available at<br />

www.wto.org/english/tratop-e/dispu-e/231abre.pdf.<br />

295. Article 30 provides for an exception to exclusive rights conferred by a patent. The provision<br />

reads as follows: "Members may provide limited exceptions to the exclusive rights conferred by a patent,<br />

provided that such exceptions do not unreasonably conflict with a normal exploitation of the patent and do<br />

not unreasonably prejudice the legitimate interests of the patent owner, taking account of the legitimate<br />

interests of third parties." Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, art. 30.<br />

Apr. 15, 1994, Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, Annex IC, 33 I.L.M.<br />

1125 (1994) [hereinafter TRIPS], available at www.wto.orgfEnglish/docs-e/legal-e/27-trips.pdf.<br />

296. Panel Report, Canada - Patent Protection of Pharmaceutical Products, para. 7.69, WT/DS 1l4/R<br />

(Mar. 17, 2000) [hereinafter Canada - Pharmaceutical Patents], available at<br />

http://www.wto.org/english/tratop e/dispu-e17428d.pdf.<br />

297. See Neumann & TOrk, supra note 5, at 226-27.<br />

298. EC- Sardines PR, supra note 291, para. 7.120.<br />

299. Id. para. 4.7.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 422 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

the panel in EC - Sardines ruled that "Members cannot create obstacles to trade<br />

which are unnecessary or which, in their application, amount to arbitrary or<br />

unjustifiable discrimination or a disguised restriction on international trade." 3<br />

The question arises whether the necessity analysis in Article 2.2 TBT should be<br />

the same as the three-step test under the SPS Agreement. According to this test,<br />

national measures will be consistent with Article 5.6 SPS if there is no alternative<br />

measure available, or if the alternative measure does not achieve the appropriate<br />

level of protection, or if it is not significantly less trade-restrictive. Due to the similar<br />

wording of the relevant provisions in the SPS and TBT Agreements, one may argue<br />

that the core necessity standards should be the same.<br />

Finally, technical regulations shall not be more trade-restrictive than necessary<br />

to fulfil a legitimate objective, "taking account of the risks non-fulfilment would<br />

create.""" There is some uncertainty about the meaning of this requirement. On the<br />

one hand, it seems like a balancing or cost-benefit-analysis test, similar to the tests<br />

adopted in Korea - Beef and EC - Asbestos (balancing of the importance of the<br />

values and policies and the extent to which the measure contributes to the aim<br />

pursued). Assessing the risks of non-fulfillment of a particular objective will be part<br />

of the necessity analysis. It may actually make the necessity requirement more<br />

relaxed and less rigid." 2 On the other hand, the term could also point towards a full<br />

proportionality test. That would allow the panel to determine whether the costs of a<br />

measure (i.e., the negative effects on international trade) are excessive or<br />

disproportionate to the risks of not fulfilling the pursued objective. A measure could<br />

therefore be disproportionate even though it is the least trade-restrictive measure.<br />

This question has not been fully clarified yet.<br />

3. Conclusion: How the Tests in the SPS and TBT Agreements Operate<br />

The TBT Agreement is deferential towards the policy objectives that WTO<br />

Members want to achieve, but it shows less deference to the means employed to<br />

achieve those objectives. This is not unusual and reflects similar normative<br />

standards in the GATT and the SPS Agreement. It can be argued that there is a<br />

broader scope for a balancing test in the TBT Agreement. Additional criteria, which<br />

are not included as such in the SPS Agreement, relate to the legitimacy of the<br />

objectives pursued and the risk of non-fulfillment of those objectives. This entails<br />

more subjectivity, or discretionary elements, permitted in a panel decision? °3<br />

It remains to be seen whether the jurisprudence interpreting the TBT<br />

Agreement will move more towards a necessity and balancing test that structurally<br />

resembles the traditional proportionality test (for instance, as applied in public<br />

international law). Weighing and balancing of protected rights and interests may<br />

take place with regard to both the legitimacy of the objectives pursued and the<br />

weight attributed to the risk of non-fulfilment of that objective.<br />

Generally, the SPS and TBT Agreements lay down positive normative<br />

standards for trade restrictive measures that go beyond the principle of non-<br />

300. Id. para. 7.120.<br />

301. Id. para. 5.15.<br />

302. ORTINO, supra note 100, at 468.<br />

303. Desmedt, supra note 4, at 459-60.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 423 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

discrimination and also apply to non-discriminatory domestic regulation. These<br />

standards provide for detailed obligations that are more sophisticated and structured<br />

than the tests applied in the GATT, in EC free movement law or in the Interstate<br />

Commerce Clause. One difference is that the tests applied in the context of EC law<br />

and the Interstate Commerce Clause have been developed and elaborated through<br />

the jurisprudence, while the tests in the SPS and TBT Agreements were explicitly<br />

written into these more modern trade agreements. The main standards in the SPS<br />

and TBT Agreements are that the domestic measures pursue an accepted public<br />

policy objective and that they are no more trade-restrictive than necessary. This<br />

determination is governed and influenced by a balancing and weighing process<br />

aiming to ensure that the obstacles to international trade are not disproportionate or<br />

excessive to the objectives pursued by the Members.<br />

VII. CONCLUSION<br />

The WTO is a developing legal system. More than ten years after its creation,<br />

many of its provisions and underlying concepts are constantly being refined by<br />

jurisprudence and scholarly writing. This process is frequently accompanied and<br />

influenced by comparative legal thinking. A comparative view, which is also the<br />

basis of this article, may contribute to clarifying uncertainties and providing some<br />

input into the thinking about WTO law. Conversely, an overly simplistic<br />

transplantation of legal concepts from one legal order to another is not what this<br />

process should be about. This would lead to misunderstandings and confusion, and<br />

it would be perceived as illegitimate. A more fruitful approach is to reflect on<br />

concepts that have developed over decades in other legal systems and to benefit<br />

from the core elements of those concepts when analysing WTO law.<br />

One of the most important challenges for WTO law is the balancing of<br />

competing rights, principles, values, or interests. The perceived juxtaposition of free<br />

trade and non-trade interests is one fundamental expression of this concern.<br />

Another concern is whether the WTO judicial bodies should do balancing at all or<br />

better leave that to national institutions. Legally, balancing in the WTO requires<br />

constant (re-)interpretation of specific provisions of the WTO Agreements which lay<br />

down the criteria to shall be taken into account by the WTO Members.<br />

The increasing demand for authoritative and sensitive balancing is a major<br />

challenge for judicial bodies that have to cope with concrete disputes. Difficult<br />

practical questions relate to the scope of WTO law, the interaction with other legal<br />

regimes, the precise meaning of open-ended provisions, or the importance of noneconomic<br />

values and interests in WTO law. Such a process requires appropriate and<br />

legitimate legal instruments for the judiciary to work with.<br />

Some dispute that there is, or that there should be, adjudication of competing<br />

values in the WTO. Others may want to cloud the issue for a variety of reasons.<br />

Judges, for instance, may favor tests, so as to avoid "the impression that there is any<br />

need to adjudicate competing values at all." 3 ' 4 In analyzing the jurisprudence and<br />

disputes, which appear rather technical at first glance, one finds many instances<br />

where such a balancing of rights, principles, values, and interests is actually taking<br />

place and can hardly be avoided.<br />

304. Howse, supra note 188, at 140.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 424 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

The main concern is how to undertake balancing within the WTO legal system.<br />

This includes the definition of the standards and tests against which this balancing<br />

may take place. Most prominent are the concepts of necessity, reasonableness, and<br />

proportionality.<br />

In our chapter on legal principles, we have concluded that one of the main<br />

characteristics of principles is the idea of optimization. Principles command that<br />

they be realized to the highest extent possible, and they do not apply in an all-ornothing<br />

fashion. In case of a conflict, two principles do not strike each other out, as<br />

is the case with rules. Both principles generally remain valid and need to be<br />

balanced against each other. One insight from this theoretical approach is to<br />

recognize that in legal orders, which lack a clear hierarchy of norms and which<br />

contain many open-ended provisions, conflicts will often be resolved through a<br />

balancing of conflicting principles. In fact, the very nature of the existence of legal<br />

principles and open-ended provisions makes balancing unavoidable. The<br />

relationship between the different values and principles laid down in the WTO<br />

Agreements is thus relative, depending on the facts of the case and the different<br />

interests at stake. Substantive tests may help structure and rationalize this process,<br />

aiming to find an equilibrium between different competing objectives.<br />

The increasing maturity of the WTO legal system has been analyzed against the<br />

background of its "constitutionalization." One particular aspect of this process is the<br />

so-called "judicial norm-generation," whereby constitutional-type principles and<br />

techniques are generated through the WTO jurisprudence."' Deborah Cass<br />

explicitly mentions the principle of proportionality, rational relationship testing, and<br />

less restrictive means. It is necessary to have an open debate about the normative<br />

content and implications of these principles in WTO law.<br />

Balancing within the WTO legal system can take place at two different levels.<br />

First, at the national level, domestic authorities are in many instances required by<br />

WTO law to take into account and weigh competing interests as part of their<br />

domestic decision-making process. Additionally, the domestic decision-making<br />

process must be transparent, open, and unbiased. This can be considered as the<br />

procedural aspect of substantive tests imposed by WTO law. Second, balancing also<br />

takes place at the WTO level, in particular in the dispute settlement proceedings.<br />

Whenever a dispute arises, the judicial bodies, applying the specific provisions of the<br />

WTO Agreements, will have to balance competing factors. This balancing process is<br />

structured and mediated by the the standards and tests discussed in this paper.<br />

Balancing is incorporated in many specific WTO provisions. Article XX<br />

GATT, for instance, consists of different steps of analysis, relating both to the design<br />

and application of domestic measures. While there is no overall balancing of<br />

competing values, the different steps of analysis within Article XX GATT each<br />

require a concrete evaluation and balancing of specific rights and interests at issue.<br />

One important function of the tests in Article XX GATT is to structure and<br />

rationalize the assessment of domestic measures. The same holds true for the SPS<br />

and TBT Agreements.<br />

The principle of proportionality plays an important role in many national and<br />

international jurisdictions. It is both a doctrine for the legislature and for the<br />

administration to follow and a standard applied by the judiciary when reviewing the<br />

305. See generally Cass, supra note 34.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 425 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:371<br />

acts of public authorities. Its normative content, including the intensity of review,<br />

may vary, but the core of any proportionality analysis remains the same. The basic<br />

idea is to limit discretion exercised by public authorities in a democratic society and<br />

to balance competing interests. Proportionality is a key principle in determining the<br />

relationship between different actors, including states vs. individuals (in domestic<br />

law), federal level vs. state level (in federal systems), and <strong>State</strong>s vs. <strong>State</strong>s (in<br />

international law). More specifically, the principle of proportionality is recognized in<br />

some systems as a general test for the exercise of free discretion. It is also used to<br />

review justifications for interference with, or restrictions on, rights. Other tests, such<br />

as necessity or reasonableness, may equally includes elements of proportionality<br />

without disclosing this factor.<br />

Proportionality analysis is closely linked to the concepts of intensity or standard<br />

of review. The experience in other legal systems has shown that intensity of review<br />

is one specific aspect of the principle of proportionality and relates to its procedural<br />

dimension (as opposed to the normative content-the substantive dimension). We<br />

therefore advocate a comprehensive assessment of the review power exercised by<br />

judges, taking into account the interwoven aspects of proportionality and intensity<br />

(or standard) of review. One can attempt to clarify these concepts by separating the<br />

procedural from the substantive aspects of judicial review and, at the same time, by<br />

outlining their interrelationship.<br />

In the WTO, proportionality is not mentioned as such in the individual<br />

Agreements and has not been explicitly recognized as a general principle. Our basic<br />

argument is that proportionality, though not recognized as such, underpins and<br />

inspires many of the specific rules laid down in the WTO Agreements.<br />

We can identify at least two possible ways how the principle of proportionality<br />

could apply in WTO law. First, proportionality as a principle of general<br />

international law may inform the interpretation of specific provisions of the WTO<br />

Agreements. Second, proportionality may be a specific obligation within the WTO<br />

Agreements, having been laid down in provisions such as Article XX GATT and<br />

similar provisions in the SPS and TBT Agreements. Those provisions often require<br />

balancing and the reliance on some sort of proportionality theory to define the<br />

specific obligations incumbent on the WTO Members.<br />

Tests like necessity, reasonableness, and proportionality are not standardized<br />

and may well lead to confusion, given that they are applied in many different legal<br />

regimes. For instance, the concept of necessity is often mentioned in the WTO<br />

Agreements as well as in other legal systems. In the traditional reading of the<br />

principle of proportionality, necessity is the second step of analysis. It does not<br />

(explicitly) include a weighing and balancing of the advantages and negative impacts<br />

of a measure. Alternatively, the use of the concept of necessity in the context of UK<br />

human rights law stands for-and includes-a fuller proportionality analysis. Public<br />

international law also includes some balancing of rights and interests to refine the<br />

concept of necessity. Within the scope of Article XX GAT, necessity is equally not<br />

restricted to a simple assessment of the least trade-restrictiveness of a domestic<br />

measure. The determination whether a trade-restrictive measure is necessary to<br />

pursue a legitimate public policy objective will be made upon a balancing of different<br />

factors as elaborated in the jurisprudence.<br />

What can be the possible consequences of a more coherent proportionality<br />

theory applied by the WTO judiciary? First, it imposes an obligation on Members to<br />

justify their measures according to a relatively structured legal criterion. It further<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 426 2006-2007


2007<br />

PROPORTIONALITY: WTO LAW IN COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE<br />

makes the judicial process more rational, coherent, and predictable. One effect is to<br />

limit the discretion of judges by requiring them to follow a sequence of steps in<br />

analyzing domestic measures. Through the three-step analysis, a structured<br />

deliberative process may take place, within which judges play a predominant role.<br />

The procedural aspect of proportionality, both in its application by domestic<br />

authorities and by the WTO judiciary, involves a "structured weighing of<br />

interests. 3 6 1 This includes the fact that all interested parties may articulate their<br />

views, which subsequently need to be taken into account in the balancing process. In<br />

that sense, the principle of proportionality may pose less of a danger to WTO<br />

Members pursuing legitimate policy choices than some other, vaguely defined tests.<br />

One counterargument against proportionality (and balancing) in the WTO<br />

context is that it often provides judges with too great a power to examine legitimate<br />

domestic measure and to interfere with sovereign policy choices. Balancing by the<br />

judiciary may promote vagueness and leave the courts a "permanent loophole,"<br />

maximizing their freedom of action. 7 Our argument is different. The more<br />

structured and rational a test, the more the courts will have to engage in a<br />

transparent judicial discourse with regard to trade-offs they are constantly required<br />

to make. Such discourse needs to take the arguments advanced by the parties more<br />

seriously. As the experience in other legal systems shows, this is no guarantee for<br />

elaborate and sophisticated judgments. Yet, it may contribute to reducing the<br />

vagueness and unpredictability of judicial reasoning in the WTO.<br />

306. de Btlrca, supra note 10, at 146.<br />

307. Donald Regan, The Supreme Court and <strong>State</strong> Protectionism: Making Sense of the Dormant<br />

Commerce Clause, 84 MICH. L. REV. 1091, 1286-87 (1986).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 427 2006-2007


HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 428 2006-2007


The Modernization of European Competition<br />

<strong>Law</strong>: A Story of Unfinished Concepts<br />

JORGEN BASEDOW*<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. D ECENTRA LIZATIO N .......................................................................................... 430<br />

II. A MORE ECONOMIC APPROACH IN MERGER CONTROL ............................... 433<br />

III. PRIVATE E NFORCEM ENT ................................................................................... 436<br />

In the late 1990s the European Commission started to conceive a complete<br />

overhaul of its competition policy. In view of the imminent enlargement of the<br />

Community to central and eastern Europe and the accession of a great number of<br />

new Member <strong>State</strong>s, the Commission feared that it would be less and less able to<br />

ensure a satisfactory degree of enforcement of European competition law. In the<br />

spring of 1999 it therefore published a White Paper that suggested an entirely new<br />

structure for the enforcement of Articles 81 and 82 EC.' Its most important effect<br />

was that it replaced the previous monopoly of the European Commission to grant<br />

exemptions under Article 81(3) with a network of national competition authorities,<br />

which would be entitled to the direct application of Article 81(3) EC. This<br />

decentralisation, which will be outlined in the first part of this paper, is accompanied<br />

by a certain change in the application of the substantive provisions. It is probably<br />

due to an increased American and Anglo-Saxon influence on European competition<br />

law that a shift towards a more economic approach can be observed. Various<br />

Commission instruments give evidence of this trend. It comes to the surface most<br />

clearly in the new Merger Control Regulation 139/2004, which will be discussed in<br />

the second part. A third spectacular change of direction became visible in late 2005<br />

and relates to private enforcement of Articles 81 and 82. The Commission had<br />

already hinted at the need for an increased use of private litigation in its early<br />

proposals for Regulation 1/2003.2 A Green Paper on this subject was published in<br />

December 2005.'<br />

Prof. Dr. h.c. Jiirgen Basedow, LL.M. (Harvard Univ.), Director of the Max Planck Institute for<br />

Comparative and International Private <strong>Law</strong>, Professor at the University Hamburg, Chairman of the<br />

German Monopoly Commission.<br />

1. Commission White Paper on Modernisation of the Rules Implementing Articles 85 and 86 of the EC<br />

Treaty, COM (99) 101 final, 1999 O.J. (C 132) 1.<br />

2. See id. paras. 99-100.<br />

3. Commission Green Paper on Damages Actions for Breach of the EC Antitrust Rules, COM (2005)<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 429 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:429<br />

I. DECENTRALIZATION<br />

Ever since the promulgation of Regulation 17 in 1962' European competition<br />

law has been characterized by the Commission's monopoly to grant exemptions<br />

under Article 81(3) EC. While national competition authorities and courts were<br />

allowed or even under an obligation to apply the prohibition of restrictive<br />

agreements laid down in Article 81(1) EC, they were not in a position to decide<br />

whether the case under scrutiny was exempted or not. Since the defendant<br />

undertakings usually invoke some justification for their anticompetitive behaviour,<br />

complaints lodged with a national competition authority or litigation started in a<br />

national court for violation of Article 81 were rather useless. Those who suffered<br />

from anticompetitive behaviour preferred to directly address the European<br />

Commission. The number of such complaints grew constantly with the accession of<br />

new Member <strong>State</strong>s, and the Commission was less and less able to efficiently enforce<br />

European competition law.<br />

The Commission used two instruments to cope with the problem. With regard<br />

to standard situations it issued block exemption regulations which declared Article<br />

81(1) inapplicable to certain categories of agreements and concerted practices.<br />

Moreover, individual applications for exemptions were more and more often<br />

answered by so-called comfort letters. Without providing for definite clearance of<br />

the respective behaviour, they would state that the Commission, while reserving the<br />

right of later investigation, did not see any reason to intervene for the time being.<br />

The resulting uncertainty was most clearly felt when contracts containing<br />

anticompetitive clauses gave rise to private litigation: Would a national judge be<br />

allowed to consider a clause covered by a comfort letter as null and void under<br />

Article 81(2) EC, or would that clause have to be respected as valid until further<br />

action would be taken by the Commission? 5<br />

In view of the imminent enlargement of the Community towards central and<br />

eastern Europe and the accession of 10 new Member <strong>State</strong>s, the Commission feared<br />

a flood of new cases would cause the situation to become untenable. It therefore<br />

gave up its monopoly on granting exemptions. Under Article 1(2) of Regulation<br />

1/2003 "agreements, decisions and concerted practices caught by Article 81(1) of the<br />

Treaty which satisfy the conditions of Article 81(3) of the Treaty shall not be<br />

prohibited, no prior decision to that effect being required., 6 At the same time the<br />

competition authorities of the Member <strong>State</strong>s are deprived of their discretion to<br />

apply either national competition law or Articles 81 and 82 when investigating<br />

anticompetitive behaviour. While the investigation as such remains discretionary,<br />

they have to apply Article 81 and 82 to behaviour that may affect trade between<br />

Member <strong>State</strong>s if they decide to initiate proceedings. 7 In respect of anticompetitive<br />

agreements, Article 3(2) explicitly establishes that Article 81 takes priority over a<br />

parallel application of national competition law. This rule and the direct<br />

672 final (Dec. 19, 2005).<br />

4. Council Regulation 17, 1962 J.O. (13) 204 (EEC); amended by Council Regulation 1216/1999, 1999<br />

O.J. (L 148) 5 (EC).<br />

5. See Schrdter, in VERTRAG OBER DIE EUROPAISCHE UNION UND VERTRAG ZUR GRONDUNG DER<br />

EUROPAISCHEN GEMEINSCHAFT - KOMMENTAR (Groeben & Schwarze eds., 6th ed. 2003), Art. 81 EC,<br />

para. 229 with further references.<br />

6. Council Regulation 1/2003, art. 1, 2003 O.J. (L 1) 7 (EC).<br />

7. See id. art. 3(1).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 430 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE MODERNIZATION OF EUROPEAN COMPETITION LAW<br />

applicability of Article 81(3) EC are supposed to prevent the distortion of the<br />

uniform substantive principles of Article 81 by the simultaneous application of<br />

national competition law.<br />

But is that presumption justified? Is the obligation to apply uniform<br />

substantive standards sufficient to ensure uniform practice? We would be prepared<br />

to accept that assumption in the context of uniform private law in, for instance, the<br />

law of the international sale of goods or in respect of international transport<br />

conventions. But in competition law national interest and political involvement are<br />

much stronger than in traditional private law. In this respect the traditions differ<br />

widely among the 25 Member <strong>State</strong>s. Economic policy in some of the old Member<br />

<strong>State</strong>s, such as France, has always focused on the support of large national<br />

corporations whereas the economic policy of other countries, in particular Great<br />

Britain and Germany, has traditionally stressed the need for a competitive<br />

environment for the sake of consumer welfare and economic freedom. In most of<br />

the new Member <strong>State</strong>s, competition law and policy are new achievements.<br />

Economic and political leaders of the older generation may have difficulty with<br />

competition policy, and the new generation sometimes appears to reject state<br />

intervention altogether even if it is meant to protect competition. The divergences<br />

are far-reaching and raise serious doubts about the possibility of a uniform<br />

competition regime under which administration is largely left to national authorities.<br />

The Commission has been aware of the risks inherent in decentralization. The<br />

concept underlying Regulation 1/2003 provides for replacement of the Commission's<br />

monopoly-not by the decisions taken by single national authorities, but by a<br />

network composed of the Commission and the competition authorities of the<br />

Member <strong>State</strong>s which are put under an obligation of close cooperation. The<br />

mechanisms of information and consultation are set forth in various provisions of<br />

Regulation 1/2003 and in further Community instruments (in particular a common<br />

declaration' and a so-called network communication). In this context only some<br />

basic structures can be explained.<br />

A basic issue relates to the allocation of cases to a national competition<br />

authority. Given the effects doctrine which has been espoused by many national<br />

competition laws of Member <strong>State</strong>s, anticompetitive behaviour affecting trade<br />

between Member <strong>State</strong>s will often give rise to investigations conducted by two or<br />

more competition authorities of different countries. Their respective competence<br />

cannot be doubted, but it goes without saying that parallel proceedings conducted in<br />

several Member <strong>State</strong>s may generate excessive costs and lead to contradictory<br />

results. Article 13 of Regulation 1/2003 therefore allows Member <strong>State</strong>s to suspend<br />

or terminate proceedings in view of proceedings initiated by the authority of another<br />

Member <strong>State</strong>. Contrary to the objection of lis alibi pendens in civil procedure, it is<br />

not necessarily the court first approached that will conduct the proceedings. Rather,<br />

the allocation of a case will be decided by a consultation between the Member <strong>State</strong>s<br />

involved and the Commission.<br />

8. Joint <strong>State</strong>ment of the Council and the Commission on the Functioning of the Network of<br />

Competition Authorities (EU) No. 15435/02 of 10 Dec. 2002.<br />

9. Commission Notice on Cooperation Within the Network of Competition Authorities (EU) of 27<br />

Apr. 2004,2004 O.J. (C 101) 43.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 431 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:429<br />

According to the network communication, the case should be allocated to the<br />

authority best suited for that purpose.'" While some relevant considerations are set<br />

forth in the communication, their mutual relation is unclear. For example, the case<br />

may be allocated to the authority of a Member <strong>State</strong> where most of the relevant<br />

proof is located, but it would also be possible for the case to be left to the authority<br />

of another Member <strong>State</strong> which has the resources for investigation at the relevant<br />

time. After two years of operation, officials of the Commission and of national<br />

competition authorities appear to be highly satisfied with the results.<br />

We know much less, however, about the evaluation by industry. The<br />

discretionary character of case allocation may generate unforeseeable risks and high<br />

costs for businesses. Take the example of criminal sanctions for the responsible<br />

managers, which exist only in some Member <strong>State</strong>s, such as Great Britain or<br />

Slovakia. Suppose that a case, which has its centre of gravity in a country such as<br />

Germany, where criminal sanctions are unknown, is allocated by the discretion of<br />

the network to the Slovak or the British competition authorities. Could we really<br />

assume that such discretionary case allocation would be in line with basic rights such<br />

as those enshrined in Article 6 of the European Human Rights Convention" and in<br />

Article 47 of the Charter of Basic Rights?' 2<br />

Regulation 1/2003 provides for many obligations in the field of information and<br />

consultation. 3 It also allows the competition authorities of Member <strong>State</strong>s to carry<br />

out investigations on behalf of the competition authority of another Member <strong>State</strong> in<br />

order to establish whether there has been an infringement of Article 81 or 82.14 It<br />

must, however, be stressed that this type of cooperation is voluntary. How can we<br />

expect a thorough investigation into a cross-border cartel if Member <strong>State</strong>s'<br />

authorities are not obligated to carry out investigation requests from the national<br />

authorities of other Member <strong>State</strong>s? The underlying assumption is that the national<br />

competition authority designated by the network is to carry out such a<br />

comprehensive inquiry into all effects of anticompetitive behaviour wherever they<br />

are felt within the Community. This assumption may be optimistic, however.<br />

Regulation 1/2003 does not put the designated competition authority under an<br />

obligation to extend its investigation beyond the national boundaries of its own state.<br />

Given the difficulties of taking evidence abroad and the delay caused by<br />

transnational cooperation, national competition authorities are likely to limit their<br />

investigations to their respective national territories. If that is true, the case<br />

allocation mechanism has to be questioned. If an anticompetitive behaviour affects<br />

several Member <strong>State</strong>s and the national authority designated by the network only<br />

investigates the effects felt in its own territory, case allocation may lead to<br />

underpunishment since the effects in other Member <strong>State</strong>s will not be taken into<br />

account by the investigating authority when fixing the amount of the fine.<br />

To sum up, decentralization may intensify the public enforcement of Articles 81<br />

and 82. On the other hand the structure of the European competition network as<br />

10. Id. at 43, para. 7.<br />

11. Convention for the Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms, Apr. 11, 1950, 213<br />

U.N.T.S. 221.<br />

12. Charter of Fundamental Rights of the European Union, Dec. 18, 2000, 2000 O.J. (C 364) 1. 20<br />

(discussing the right to an effective remedy and to a fair trial).<br />

13. See, e.g., Council Regulation 1/2003, supra note 6, arts. 11, 12 and 15; see also Commission Notice<br />

on Cooperation, supra note 9, art. 2.2 (discussing concrete mechanisms of cooperation).<br />

14. See id. art. 22.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 432 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE MODERNIZATION OF EUROPEAN COMPETITION LAW<br />

enshrined in Regulation 1/2003 is conceptually incomplete and inconsistent; it will<br />

most probably lead to underpunishment. This is underpinned by the final<br />

observation that there is no mutual recognition and enforcement of decisions within<br />

this network of competition authorities. Regulation 1/2003 is no more than a first<br />

step towards a true network of competition authorities.<br />

II.<br />

A MORE ECONOMIC APPROACH IN MERGER CONTROL<br />

A second distinctive feature of the modernization of EC competition law is the<br />

increased significance of economics. Clear evidence for this shift in methodology<br />

can be found in the guidelines on horizontal cooperation 6 and in the block<br />

exemption Regulation for vertical restraints. 7 But the most significant legal<br />

instrument that reflects this evolution is the substantive test of merger control<br />

adopted by the new Merger Control Regulation no. 139/2004."<br />

The control of concentrations has been introduced into Community law by<br />

Regulation 4064/89.9 Under its Article 2(3), a concentration "which creates or<br />

strengthens a dominant position as a result of which effective competition would be<br />

significantly impeded" had to be declared incompatible with the common market.<br />

The second element of this two-tiered test turned out to be rather insignificant in its<br />

practical application. Whenever the Commission assessed the creation or<br />

strengthening of an individual or collective dominant position, a significant<br />

impediment of effective competition was presumed to result therefrom. 2 ' The<br />

dominance test was inherently linked to Article 82: if the abuse of a dominant<br />

position is forbidden under that provision, the law should be reluctant to accept the<br />

emergence of dominant positions except for the case of internal growth. As a<br />

consequence of Regulation 4064/89, the same concept of dominance of the relevant<br />

market could be used for both merger control and the control of abusive practices.<br />

In particular, the judicial presumption of dominance flowing from a market share of<br />

more than fifty percent 2 ' and the test of collective dominance espoused by the Court<br />

of Justice 22 could be used in both contexts 3<br />

15. See, e.g.. Doris Hildebrand, Der "more economic approach," in DER WETTBEWERBSPOLITIK -<br />

DYNAMIK UND AUSBLICK 513 (2005); ARNDT CHRISTIANSEN, DIE "OKONOMISIERUNG" DER EU-<br />

FUSIONSKONTROLLE: MEHR KOSTEN ALS NUTZEN? 285 (2005); ULF BOGE, DER "MORE ECONOMIC<br />

APPROACH" UND DIE DEUTSCHE WETTBEWERBSPOLITIK 727 (2004).<br />

16. Commission Notice: Guidelines on the Applicability of Article 81 of the EC Treaty to Horizontal<br />

Cooperation Agreements, 2001 O.J. (C 3) 2 (EC) [hereinafter Commission Notice: Guidelines].<br />

17. Commission Regulation 2790/1999, 1999 O.J. (L 336) 21 (EC).<br />

18. Council Regulation 139/2004, 2004 O.J. (L 24) 1 (EC).<br />

19. Council Regulation 4064/89, 1989 O.J. (L 395), 1 (EEC).<br />

20. For the discussion on the relevance of this element, see Immenga, in Immenga/Mestmacker, EG-<br />

Wettbewerbsrecht, Vol. 1 (1997), Art. 2 FKVO, para. 18 seqq.; R6sler, in Frankfurter Kommentar zum<br />

Kartellrecht, Vol. 6, Art. 2 FKVO, para. 216 seq.<br />

21. See, e.g., Case C-85/76, Hoffmann-La Roche v. Comm'n, 1979 E.C.R. 1-461; Case C-62/86, AKZO<br />

Chemie v. Comm'n, 1991 E.C.R. 1-03359 (both concerning abuse of dominance law).<br />

22. See, e.g., Joined Cases T-68/89, T-77/89 & T-78/89 Societa Italiana Vetro SpA v. Comm'n, 1992<br />

E.C.R. 11-1403; Case C-393/92, Almelo v. NV Energiebedrijf Ijsselmij, 1994 E.C.R. 1-1477; Joined Cases C-<br />

140/94, C-141/94 & C-142/94, DIP SpA v. Comune di Bassano del Grappa, 1995 E.C.R. 1-3257; Joined<br />

Cases T-24/93, T-25/93, T-26/93 & T-28/93, Compagnie Maritime Beige Transports SA v. Comm'n, 1996<br />

E.C.R. 1-1201; Joined Cases C-68/94 & C-30/95, French Republic v. Comm'n, 1998 E.C.R. 1-1375; Case T-<br />

102/96, Gencor Ltd. v. Comm'n, 1999 E.C.R. 11-753; Case T-342/99, Airtours plc v. Comm'n, 2002 E.C.R.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 433 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:429<br />

Article 2(3) of Regulation 139/2004 has changed the order of the two elements<br />

of the substantive test of merger control. At present, a concentration "which would<br />

significantly impede effective competition ... in particular as a result of the creation<br />

or strengthening of a dominant position, shall be declared incompatible with the<br />

common market., 24 Under the new rule the dominance test is only an example for a<br />

significant impediment of effective competition. The latter now provides the main<br />

criterion. As a consequence, even a merger that does not satisfy the dominance test<br />

can be prohibited under the new SIEC test.<br />

This amendment may appear marginal at first sight. But it has the effect of<br />

depriving the previous case law of much of its significance. Given the impediment to<br />

economic competition exemplified by the dominance test, it is unlikely that a merger<br />

that satisfies the latter will be declared compatible with the common market. On the<br />

other hand, the application of the dominance test is not exhaustive. There may be<br />

mergers that are not caught by the dominance test that still constitute a significant<br />

impediment to economic competition.<br />

In order to explain the need for this additional possibility of control, recital 25<br />

of Regulation 139/2004 refers to the non-coordinated or unilateral effects that a<br />

merger may have in oligopolistic markets. A good illustration of these<br />

uncoordinated effects is the Airtours case, decided by the Court of First Instance. 25<br />

It relates to the British market of all-inclusive tours to the European continent and<br />

its surroundings. Among the four leading tour operators, numbers three and four,<br />

with market shares of 15 and 19.4% respectively, had merged. 26 As a consequence,<br />

the merged entity was now number one, with a 34.4% market share; this placed it in<br />

front of the previous leader, which had a 30.7% market share, and the fourth<br />

company, which had a 20.4% market share. 27 The Commission had prohibited the<br />

merger, stating that it would strengthen a collective dominant position of the four<br />

leading undertakings." On review, the Commission decision was declared void by<br />

the Court of First Instance. The Court pointed out that, for the assumption of<br />

collective dominance, considerable transparency of the market would be required so<br />

that every member of the leading oligopoly could monitor with sufficient precision<br />

and speed the behaviour of other market actors. 2 9 Moreover, collective dominance<br />

would require the ability of the members of the oligopoly to impose severe sanctions<br />

on deviating members, therefore discouraging them from any attempt to push<br />

forward in competition." The Court held that the Commission had not sufficiently<br />

proven the presence of these elements of collective dominance in the case at hand. 3<br />

It is not unlikely that the collective dominance test has reached its limits in this<br />

case. Apparently, one of the basic requirements of collective dominance, i.e., the<br />

11-2585 [hereinafter Airtours].<br />

23. In assessing market shares, one has to be aware, however, that due to the prospective character<br />

and the more dynamic approach of merger control, the ECJ decisions on Article 82 concerning the field of<br />

abuse of dominance can only cautiously be transferred to the situation of merger control; see Immenga,<br />

supra note 20, art. 2 FKVO, para. 102.<br />

24. Council Regulation 139/2004, supra note 18, art. 2(3).<br />

25. Airtours, supra note 22.<br />

26. Id. para. 66.<br />

27. Id.<br />

28. Commission Decision 2000/276, 2000 O.J. (L 93) 1, 9 (EC).<br />

29. Airtours, supra note 22, para. 60.<br />

30. Id. para. 62.<br />

31. Id. para. 277.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 434 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE MODERNIZATION OF EUROPEAN COMPETITION LAW<br />

homogeneous character of the goods in the market, is absent here. Nevertheless,<br />

economists maintain that a merger in a narrow oligopoly may provide additional<br />

room to manoeuvre for the remaining undertakings in the market. In particular, a<br />

competitive initiative taken by a tour operator with a very large market share would<br />

be unlikely to be matched by its competitors who would be unable to book a<br />

sufficient number of hotel rooms and air transport capacity to strike back.<br />

Unilateral effects of this kind are said to be unsusceptible of being accounted for by<br />

the dominance test. Economists suggest that the SIEC test is more flexible and<br />

would allow for a prohibition needed in these cases. 32 While this may be true, the<br />

economic reasoning underlying the analysis of the Airtours case appears<br />

questionable. It is based on a very limited time frame of one year and does not take<br />

into account the reaction of competitors in subsequent years. It is possible that<br />

competitors who have been surprised by the market leader pushing forward in one<br />

year will strike back in the following year. If that is true, the need for merger review<br />

beyond the dominance test would not appear to be well founded.<br />

Another element of economic analysis that has received increased significance<br />

in the framework of the SIEC test is the efficiency defence. 33 The previous<br />

Regulation 4064/89 had pointed out, in recitals 4 and 13, that concentrations are apt<br />

to increase the competitiveness of European industry, to improve the conditions of<br />

growth, to raise the standard of living, and to strengthen the Community's economic<br />

and social cohesion. But these goals were related to the fundamental objectives of<br />

the Community as laid down in Articles 2 and 130(a) (now 158) EC, while the<br />

efficiency gains to be derived from a merger were not explicitly addressed. Those<br />

gains could give support to a merger insofar as they contributed to "the development<br />

of technical and economic progress. ' But their role was ambivalent since they<br />

might also be suited to give additional strength to the merged entity in relation to its<br />

competitors.<br />

To the contrary, the Green Paper on the overhaul of the merger control<br />

Regulation 35 makes reference to efficiency gains only in defence of concentration, as<br />

does Regulation 139/2004. While the wording of Article 2(1) has remained<br />

unchanged in this respect, recital 29 makes explicit reference to the possibility "that<br />

the efficiencies brought about by the concentration counteract the effects on<br />

competition, and in particular the potential harm to consumers ... and that, as a<br />

consequence, the concentration would not significantly impede effective competition<br />

.... ,,36 Thus, efficiency is considered as an element of the restriction of competition,<br />

and the guidelines on horizontal mergers published by the Commission 3 point<br />

equally to the possibility that efficiency gains will offset anticompetitive effects.<br />

32. See Bundeskartellamt, Arbeitskreis Kartellrecht, Das Untersagungskriterium in der<br />

Fusionskontrolle - Marktbeherrschende Stellung versus Substantial Lessening of Competition?, Konzepte<br />

fuir die Prufung von Unternehmenszusammenschltissen 16 (2001).<br />

33. See MESTMACKER & SCHWEITZER, EUROPAISCHES WETTBEWERBSRECHT § 25, para. 142 (2d<br />

ed. 2004); Zeise, in HANDBUCH DER FUSIONSKONTROLLE 358. para. 1282 (Schulte ed., 2005).<br />

34. Council Regulation 4064/89, supra note 19. art. 2(1)(b) (EC).<br />

35. Commission Green Paper on the Review of Council Regulation. No. 4064/89, COM (2001) 745/6<br />

final (Nov. 12, 2001).<br />

36. Council Regulation 139/2004, supra note 18, recital 29.<br />

37. Commission Notice: Guidelines, supra note 16.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 435 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:429<br />

There are two major objections to the new approach. In the first place, the very<br />

measurement of efficiency gains by a state authority appears to contradict the model<br />

of the market economy. This model departs from the basic assumption that market<br />

actors-whether individuals or undertakings-determine their own economic<br />

preferences individually and in a subjective way. There is no rational way of<br />

convincing an individual that the purchase of a Rolls Royce has to be preferred to<br />

that of a Skoda. It is not possible to find objective criteria that cause people to<br />

spend their money on large apartments instead of luxury cars. These individual<br />

preferences may be explained by psychological and cultural factors, or by specific<br />

needs and inclinations of the single market actors. But the market process has to<br />

accept these preferences as a point of departure, i.e., for the exchange of goods and<br />

services and the formation of prices. As a consequence, efficiency gains can only be<br />

determined on the basis of individual decisions to pay a certain price for goods or<br />

services. Efficiency is the aggregate of the increase of satisfaction felt by market<br />

actors as a result of the market process. In this respect, it is not sufficient to take<br />

into account the satisfaction of the undertakings involved in a merger; the<br />

satisfaction of third parties and consumers has to be considered as well. How can a<br />

state authority assess all these individual appreciations of a merger? Since the<br />

individual appreciation would usually depend on the prediction of the effect of a<br />

merger in the future, prognostic capacities of which nobody can boast would be<br />

required.<br />

A second objection relates to the alleged offsetting of the anticompetitive and<br />

efficiency effects of a merger. This would require a kind of quantification of both<br />

effects which is, in fact, insinuated in the Commission's guidelines on horizontal<br />

mergers. But such quantification would unnecessarily limit the analysis. It would<br />

focus on the merger's effect on prices, predicting efficiency gains if prices decrease,<br />

and prevailing anticompetitive effects if prices increase. It risks excluding the<br />

structural effects of the merger that would usually last for a much longer period than<br />

the immediate effect on prices. It should not be forgotten, however, that the review<br />

of mergers was introduced precisely for those structural effects which are reflected<br />

by the dominance test.<br />

To sum up, the more economic approach as applied by Regulation 139/2004 to<br />

the review of mergers raises many questions. It appears doubtful whether the<br />

amendment helps to protect competition, and its impact on the legal certainty<br />

required for merger operations is equally doubtful. 38 It is safe to assume, however,<br />

that the bar specializing in competition law will acquire additional business.<br />

III. PRIVATE ENFORCEMENT<br />

A further element of the modernization of EC competition law may be a shift<br />

towards private enforcement. Private enforcement has always been contemplated as<br />

a shield against private claims as far as the function of Article 81 is concerned. 9 In<br />

fact, claims arising from anticompetitive agreements have always been countered by<br />

defendants invoking the nullity of the contract under Article 81(2) EC. The recent<br />

debate focuses on the offensive use of Articles 81 and 82 as a "sword" in the hands<br />

of the victims of anticompetitive behaviour. It is well-known that private claims for<br />

38. See also Christiansen, supra note 15.<br />

39. See, e.g., K. Schmidt, supra note 20, art. 85, para. 38.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 436 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE MODERNIZATION OF EUROPEAN COMPETITION LAW<br />

compensation of the losses suffered from cartels and monopolistic abuses play a<br />

significant role in the enforcement of U.S. antitrust law, where the plaintiff is entitled<br />

to three times the amount of his loss. 4 ° In Europe, such claims have not been<br />

recognized until recently in Community law. While Member <strong>State</strong>s would usually<br />

provide for a cause of action for damages resulting from the violation of Articles 81<br />

and 82 EC in their municipal laws, no Member <strong>State</strong> is as generous to the plaintiff as<br />

U.S. law.<br />

As early as 1999, when presenting the proposal for the later Regulation 1/2003,<br />

the Commission pointed out that the "proposal aims at promoting private<br />

enforcement through national courts."'<br />

' , In fact, the direct applicability of Article<br />

81(3) allows national courts to give judgement on actions for compensation based<br />

upon the violation of Article 81 EC without staying proceedings, until the<br />

Commission decides upon a possible exemption under Article 81(3) EC. But at that<br />

stage there was no cause of action under Community law for such claims. This<br />

changed in September 2001, when the European Court of Justice handed down its<br />

opinion in Courage v. Crehan.<br />

42 The Court pointed out that the practical effect of<br />

the prohibition of restrictive agreements in Article 81(1) "would be put at risk if it<br />

were not open to any individual to claim damages for loss caused to him by a<br />

contract or by conduct liable to restrict or distort competition." 43 In the Court's<br />

view, "actions for damages before the national courts can make a significant<br />

contribution to the maintenance of effective competition in the Community." 4 4<br />

However, "in the absence of Community rules governing the matter" the Court<br />

referred such claims to the domestic legal systems of the single Member <strong>State</strong>s.<br />

The explicit reference to the lack of Community rules was immediately<br />

understood by the Commission. It placed an order for a comprehensive comparative<br />

survey with the international law firm Ashurst; the report was published on the<br />

website of the Directorate General Competition in 2004.46 Thereafter, it convened<br />

an expert group consisting of five judges and scholars to give advice on the various<br />

issues raised by private enforcement. 47 The resulting Green Paper on the matter was<br />

published in December 2005. '<br />

40. Clayton Act, ch. 323, § 4, 38 Stat. 730 (1914) (current version at 15 U.S.C. § 15(a) (2006)).<br />

41. Commission Proposal for a Council Regulation on the Implementation of the Rules on Competition<br />

Laid Down in Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty ("Regulation implementing Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty"),<br />

at 6, COM (2000) 582 final (Sept. 27, 2000).<br />

42. Case C-453/99, Courage Ltd. v. Crehan, 2001 E.C.R. 1-6297.<br />

43. Id. para. 26.<br />

44. Id. para. 27.<br />

45. Id. para. 29.<br />

46. Denis Waelbroeck, Donald Slater, & Gil Even-Shoshan, Study on the Conditions of Claims for<br />

Damages in Case of Infringement of EC Competition Rules, available at<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/cartels/studies/comparative-report-clean-en.pdf.<br />

47. The members of the group were Professor Walter van Gerven (Belgium), a former Advocate<br />

General of the Court of Justice as chairman, and JiIrgen Basedow, the author of the present article, Sir<br />

Christopher Bellamy (United Kingdom), President of the British Competition Appeals Tribunal, Carole<br />

Champalaune (France), judge at the French Supreme Court, and Professor Robert Mok (Netherlands).<br />

48. Commission Green Paper on Damages Actions for Breach of the EC Antitrust Rules, supra note 3.<br />

For an appraisal of the Green Paper see PRIVATE ENFORCEMENT OF EC COMPETITION LAW (Basedow<br />

ed. 2007).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 437 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:429<br />

It follows that the law in this field has not developed as far as it has regarding<br />

decentralization and the more economic approach. It is therefore too early to go<br />

into details. But it is worth raising some questions that might help foster<br />

understanding for the considerable difficulties of private enforcement. Given the<br />

coexistence of Articles 81 and 82 on the one side and national competition law on<br />

the other, the Commission must clarify the relation between Community and<br />

national law. Accordingly, it will have to decide whether the approximation of<br />

national laws or the creation of a uniform liability regime is appropriate. Since<br />

Community law will be somehow embedded in national private law, it will be<br />

important to know which national law should supplement a Community instrument.<br />

This issue of private international law will have to be answered in view of the<br />

proposal for a Rome II Regulation 49 on the law applicable to non-contractual<br />

obligations, which will be adopted and promulgated shortly.<br />

A further basic issue relates to the type of claim that is to be granted to the<br />

victims of a cartel: Should the undertakings involved in anticompetitive behaviour be<br />

put under an obligation to make restitution of the rent earned from the cartel, as a<br />

kind of unjust enrichment? Or should the victims be entitled to claim damages for<br />

compensation of their losses? The most important question that arises in this<br />

context deals with the so called passing-on defence of the cartel members." If the<br />

victims have not suffered any loss because they were able to pass the higher input<br />

prices on to their customers, should this exclude their claims? In that case it would<br />

be up to the clients on the downstream market, and perhaps eventually the<br />

consumers, to claim compensation from the undertakings involved in<br />

anticompetitive practices. Since the losses dissipate as the goods are traded<br />

downstream, they get smaller and smaller and experience shows that the final<br />

consumers do not have sufficient incentive to file an action for compensation. If the<br />

plea of the European Court of Justice for full effectiveness of Article 81 is to be<br />

taken seriously, the law must therefore allow for some kind of aggregation of small<br />

claims in a class action or other type of group action. Other issues would relate to<br />

the alleviation of proof, to the interest owed by the cartel members on the<br />

compensation, and to additional incentives which potential plaintiffs would need in<br />

order to bring action, i.e., eventually to the recognition of double or treble damages.<br />

It is my impression that the European Commission is pushing forward<br />

impatiently in this field, as it has done in the other fields mentioned before. The<br />

Green Paper is based on thorough research into the antecedents of comparative and<br />

Community law. But it is uncertain whether all the concepts and options are well<br />

thought-out. Here, as in the other fields, a certain trend of Community policy<br />

49. Commission Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and the Council on the <strong>Law</strong><br />

Applicable to Non-Contractual Obligations (Rome 11), COM (2003) 427 final (Jul. 22, 2003); Commission<br />

Amended Proposal for a European Parliament and Council Regulation on the <strong>Law</strong> Applicable to Non-<br />

Contractual Obligations ("Rome II"), COM (2006) 83 final (Feb. 21, 2006). For an appraisal of the 2003<br />

proposal in general, see, von Hein, Die Kodifikation des europdiischen Internationalen Deliktsrechts - Zur<br />

geplanten EU-Verordnung iiber das auf auf3ervertragliche Schuldverhdltnisse anzuwendende Recht, 102<br />

ZVGLRWIsS 528 (2003); for background specifically on private enforcement of EC competition law, see<br />

Hamburg Group for Private International <strong>Law</strong>, Comments on the European Commission's Draft Proposal<br />

for a Council Regulation on the <strong>Law</strong> Applicable to Non-Contractual Obligations, 67 RABELS ZEITSCHRIFF<br />

FUR AUSLANDISCHES UND INTERNATIONALES PRIVATRECHT 1 (2003): see also Bulst, Internationale<br />

ZustAndigkeit, anwendbares Recht und Schadensberechnung im Kartelldeliktsrecht, EWS 2004 403 (408).<br />

At the time of reading the proofs of this article a compromise on Rome I has been reached and the<br />

promulgation of the instrument is imminent.<br />

50. See, e.g., Roth, in 3 FRANKFURTER KOMMENTAR ZUM KARTELLRECHT § 33, para. 143.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 438 2006-2007


2007 THE MODERNIZATION OF EUROPEAN COMPETITION LAW 439<br />

becomes visible: one that gives greater weight to setting a new policy afloat than to a<br />

thorough investigation into its consequences. The Community should avoid the<br />

premature implementation of another unfinished concept. It is now up to the<br />

European public to subject the Green Paper to close scrutiny.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 439 2006-2007


HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 440 2006-2007


Corporate Gatekeeper Liability in Canada<br />

STEPHANIE BEN-ISHAI"<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. INTRO D U CTIO N ................................................................................................... 442<br />

II. CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY THEORY ............................................. 443<br />

III. THE CANAD IAN SYSTEM .................................................................................... 445<br />

A . C om m on L aw .............................................................................................. 446<br />

B . Statutory L iability ........................................................................................ 448<br />

i. C orporate Statutes ............................................................................... 448<br />

ii. Securities Statutes ................................................................................. 450<br />

iii. Secondary M arket Liability ................................................................. 453<br />

C. O ther R egulatory Regim es .......................................................................... 454<br />

i. Provincial Securities Commissions ..................................................... 454<br />

ii. Market Regulation Services Inc ......................................................... 456<br />

iii. Professional Regulatory Bodies .......................................................... 457<br />

a. Provincial <strong>Law</strong> Societies ............................................................... 457<br />

b. Investment Dealers Association of Canada ............................... 458<br />

c. Provincial Institutes of Chartered Accountants ........................ 460<br />

d. International Organization of Securities Commission .............. 461<br />

D. Criminal and Quasi-Criminal Liability ..................................................... 462<br />

IV. LOCATING THE CANADIAN SYSTEM IN AN INTERNATIONAL CONTEXT ....... 465<br />

A . D irecto rs ....................................................................................................... 465<br />

B . L a w y ers ............................................................<br />

466<br />

C . A u d ito rs ........................................................................................................ 467<br />

D . C redit R ating A gencies ................................................................................ 469<br />

LL.B., LL.M. (Harvard), Associate Professor, Osgoode Hall <strong>Law</strong> School of York University,<br />

Toronto, Canada. Parts of this article are drawn from research undertaken by the author for the Task<br />

Force to Modernize Securities Legislation in Canada. The research assistance provided by Zohar Levy and<br />

Val Culp is gratefully acknowledged. Colleagues at the 13 h <strong>Biennial</strong> Conference for the International<br />

Academy for Commercial and Consumer <strong>Law</strong>, August 9-12, University of Texas School of <strong>Law</strong>, and the<br />

2006 <strong>Meeting</strong>s of the Canadian <strong>Law</strong> and Economics Association, University of Toronto, Faculty of <strong>Law</strong>,<br />

September 29-30, 2006 provided most helpful comments on earlier drafts of this paper. The author is<br />

particularly grateful to Jacob Zeigel and Poonam Puri for comments. All errors are my own.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 441 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

E . Financial A nalysts ....................................................................................... 469<br />

F. R etail Investm ent A dvisors ......................................................................... 471<br />

G . U n derw riters ................................................................................................ 472<br />

V . C O N C LU SIO N ....................................................................................................... 472<br />

I. INTRODUCTION<br />

A series of significant reforms with respect to the legal treatment of corporate<br />

gatekeepers have taken place over the last five years in a number of countries<br />

around the world. This article serves as a taking-stock exercise of the current<br />

gatekeeper liability regime in Canada, supplemented by an examination of the<br />

options for dealing with corporate gatekeepers presented in other jurisdictions, most<br />

notably the United <strong>State</strong>s and the United Kingdom. The two primary forms of<br />

liability in the Canadian system are civil liability, through both common law and<br />

statutes, and administrative liability, found in various regulatory regimes for the<br />

different types of gatekeepers. There is also the possibility of criminal or quasicriminal<br />

liability for many gatekeepers. This article suggests that the polycentric<br />

system in which there are multiple sources of liability for gatekeepers is effective in a<br />

Canadian context. While there is an international trend towards increased<br />

streamlined government regulation of gatekeepers, as demonstrated in the U.S. and<br />

U.K., it is not a system that should be adopted by Canada. Ultimately, though the<br />

Canadian system is imperfect, this article concludes that the current Canadian<br />

regime is best suited to provide gatekeepers with guidance and incentives to perform<br />

their gatekeeping function while facilitating the competitiveness of Canadian capital<br />

markets. The key challenges with the current model center on the legitimacy and<br />

independence of the sources of liability.<br />

For the purpose of this article, corporate gatekeepers are defined as third<br />

parties who can disrupt misconduct by withholding support. The categories of<br />

corporate gatekeeper considered in this article are directors, lawyers, auditors,<br />

underwriters, credit rating agencies (CRAs), financial analysts, and retail investment<br />

advisors (RIAs). In this article, gatekeeper liability includes civil, administrative,<br />

and criminal sanctions that can be imposed on gatekeepers who fail to withhold<br />

support. This includes rules that can be enforced by public regulators and also rules<br />

that can be enforced by private parties like investors. The sources of law reviewed<br />

are statute (corporate and securities), common law, self-regulatory organizations'<br />

(SROs) rules, and rules of professional conduct set by industry bodies. The focus of<br />

this article is on gatekeepers of public companies.<br />

Part II provides a theoretical framework of corporate gatekeeper liability,<br />

through a survey of previous academic writing on the subject. For example, the<br />

works of Reinier Kraakman and John C. Coffee Jr. are considered in this section.<br />

Part III examines the sources of corporate gatekeeper liability at common law in<br />

Canada, including civil liability, statutory liability, and other regulatory regimes such<br />

as those put into place by provincial law societies. In Part IV, the author deals with<br />

each category of gatekeeper separately and suggests reforms to improve the<br />

Canadian system. A comparison with the United <strong>State</strong>s and United Kingdom<br />

informs this analysis. Part V concludes.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 442 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

II.<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY THEORY<br />

In the 1980s, Reinier Kraakman published two articles that expanded on the<br />

concept of "gatekeeper liability," which he defined as liability imposed on private<br />

parties who are able to disrupt misconduct by withholding their support from<br />

wrongdoers.' This support-which might include a specialized good, service, or form<br />

of certification that is essential for a wrongdoer to succeed-"is the 'gate' that the<br />

gatekeeper keeps." 2 True gatekeeper liability is designed to enlist the support of<br />

outside participants in the firm when controlling managers commit offences; the first<br />

requisite for gatekeeper liability is an outsider who can influence controlling<br />

managers to forgo offences.' As outsiders to the firm, these professionals are less<br />

likely to risk their reputations over fraudulent or suspicious transactions. Kraakman<br />

identified outside directors, accountants, lawyers, and underwriters as potential<br />

targets for gatekeeper liability strategies: they each have access to information about<br />

firm misconduct, they already perform a private monitoring service on behalf of the<br />

capital markets, and they face incentives that differ from those of managers (that is,<br />

they are likely to have less to gain and more to lose from firm misconduct than inside<br />

managers).' Like other liability regimes, gatekeeping imposes costs; Kraakman<br />

examines whether legal rules can induce gatekeepers to prevent misconduct at an<br />

"acceptable price." ' After outlining possible costs of a gatekeeping model,<br />

Kraakman suggests ways to adjust these costs, such as limiting penalties that<br />

gatekeepers face for breach of duty or selecting prescribed duties for gatekeepers to<br />

undertake. 6 Finally, Kraakman canvasses other enforcement strategies and<br />

concludes that gatekeepers' response to misconduct, by withholding support, has<br />

significant advantages over other third-party enforcement duties. 7<br />

For Kraakman, legal duties should be imposed on intermediaries to act as<br />

gatekeepers in certain markets, due to defects in the ability of parties to contract or<br />

ascertain the reputation of different intermediaries! Stephen Choi, however, argues<br />

that Kraakman's argument "fails to take into account the impact of different<br />

screening accuracies in the market, the incentives of intermediaries to invest in<br />

accuracy, the ex ante response of producers to the possibility of certification, and<br />

potential market defects." 9 Choi argues that "gatekeeper liability is too heavyhanded<br />

a response"' and instead advocates for less intervention through a system of<br />

self-tailored liability, a regime where "lawmakers may allow intermediaries to<br />

choose for themselves the specific duties that they will be held accountable ....""<br />

1. Reinier H. Kraakman. Gatekeepers: The Anatomy of a Third-Party Enforcement Strategy 2 J. L.<br />

ECON. & ORG. 53, 54 (1986) [hereinafter Kraakman, Gatekeepers]: see also Reinier H. Kraakman,<br />

Corporate Liability and the Costs of Legal Controls 93 YALE L.J. 857 (1984) [hereinafter Kraakman,<br />

Corporate Liability].<br />

2. Kraakman, Gatekeepers, supra note 1, at 54.<br />

3. Kraakman, Corporate Liability, supra note 1, at 890.<br />

4. Id. at 891.<br />

5. Kraakman, Gatekeepers, supra note 1, at 75.<br />

6. Id. at 79-81.<br />

7. Id. at 85.<br />

8. Id. at 93-100.<br />

9. Stephen Choi. Market Lessons for Gatekeepers. 92 Nw.U. L. REV. 916, 918 (1998).<br />

10. Id.<br />

11. Id. at 951.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 443 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

More recently, John C. Coffee, Jr. has popularized Kraakman's concept in the<br />

aftermath of Enron and other corporate scandals. Coffee has blamed such scandals<br />

on the failure of gatekeepers, who, he asserts, allowed management to engage in<br />

fraud. 12 Coffee has defined gatekeepers as independent professionals who act as<br />

reputational intermediaries, providing verification or certification services to<br />

investors. 3 Gatekeepers have less incentive to deceive; therefore, the market views<br />

gatekeepers' assurances as more credible. Their credibility also stems from the fact<br />

that gatekeepers pledge their reputational capital. 1 4 Theoretically, a gatekeeper<br />

would not sacrifice the reputational capital built up over many years of performing<br />

services for a single client or a modest fee. However, there are instances where<br />

reliance on gatekeepers may be misplaced, such as: where there is a sudden decline<br />

in the deterrent threat facing gatekeepers and they are thus more willing to take<br />

risks; where greater inducements are offered to gatekeepers to breach their duties;<br />

or where certain market scenarios lessen injury to a gatekeeper's reputation. 5<br />

Included amongst Coffee's list of gatekeepers are auditors, credit rating agencies,<br />

securities analysts, investment bankers, and securities lawyers. 6 Coffee concludes<br />

that the creation of excessive liability might cause the market for gatekeeping<br />

services to fail; instead, he advocates a shift towards stricter liability standards with a<br />

ceiling on gatekeeper liability adequate to deter misconduct. 7<br />

Whereas Coffee's proposed system is essentially regulatory, Frank Partnoy<br />

advocates a contractual system based on a percentage of the issuer's liability.<br />

Under Partnoy's proposed regime, gatekeepers would be strictly liable for any of the<br />

issuer's securities fraud damages pursuant to a settlement or judgment. 9 Although<br />

gatekeepers would not have available to them due diligence defenses, they could<br />

limit their liability by agreeing to and disclosing a percentage limitation on the scope<br />

of their liability. Authors such as Larry Ribstein oppose mandatory personal<br />

liability for professionals as a relatively ineffective way to encourage professional<br />

firms to perform their duties to clients and others. 2 ' Ribstein argues that this liability<br />

is based on "an attenuated notion of responsibility and unrealistic assumptions about<br />

12. John C. Coffee, Jr., Understanding Enron: "It's About the Gatekeepers, Stupid", 57 BUS. LAW.<br />

1403 (2001-2002); JOHN C. COFFEE, JR., GATEKEEPERS: THE ROLE OF THE PROFESSIONS IN CORPORATE<br />

GOVERNANCE (CLARENDON LECTURES IN MANAGEMENT STUDIES) (Oxford University Press 2006)<br />

(attributing the corporate failures of the 1990s to a decline in exposure to gatekeeper liability and the<br />

increase of acquiescence in clients' demands); John C. Coffee, Jr., Gatekeeper Failure and Reform: The<br />

Challenge of Fashioning Relevant Reforms (Columbia <strong>Law</strong> Sch. Ctr. for <strong>Law</strong> and Econ., Working Paper<br />

No. 237, 2003) [hereinafter Coffee, Gatekeeper Failure and Reform].<br />

13. Coffee, Gatekeeper Failure and Reform, supra note 12, at 12.<br />

14. Id. at 13.<br />

15. See generally Coffee, Gatekeeper Failure and Reform, supra note 12 (discussing in detail reasons<br />

for gatekeeper failure). See also John C. Coffee Jr., The Acquiescent Gatekeeper: Reputational<br />

Intermediaries, Auditor Independence and the Governance of Accounting (Columbia <strong>Law</strong> Sch. Ctr. for <strong>Law</strong><br />

and Econ., Working Paper No. 191, 2001) (expanding on why gatekeepers might be undermotivated to<br />

protect their reputations) [hereinafter Coffee, The Acquiescent Gatekeeper].<br />

16. Coffee Gatekeeper Failure and Reform, supra note 12.<br />

17. Id. at 67-68.<br />

18. Frank Partnoy, Strict Liability for Gatekeepers: A Reply to Professor Coffee (Univ. of S.D. Sch. of<br />

<strong>Law</strong>, <strong>Law</strong> and Econ. Research Paper Series, Paper 5, 2004).<br />

19. Frank Partnoy, Barbarians at the Gatekeepers?: A Proposal for a Modified Strict Liability Regime<br />

79 WASH. U. L. Q. 491 (2001).<br />

20. Id.<br />

21. Larry Ribstein, Limited Liability of Professional Firms after Enron, 29 J. CORP. LAW 427, 429<br />

(2004).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 444 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

firm members' ability to monitor., 2 Furthermore, he suggests, imposing personal<br />

liability on professionals may increase agency costs between professionals and their<br />

clients; affect professional firm size, structure and scope; and reduce desirable<br />

liability of the firm. 23 In relation to auditors, <strong>Law</strong>rence Cunningham prescribes a<br />

framework that uses financial statement insurance as an alternative to financial<br />

statement auditing backed by auditor liability." In his proposed framework,<br />

companies could opt for either model, subject to investor approval. 2 Financial<br />

statement insurance policies would cover damages arising from audit failuredamages<br />

due to financial misstatements that auditors did not discover-replacing<br />

auditor and issuer liability. 26<br />

In the broader context of the regulation of gatekeepers, Richard Painter<br />

stresses the balancing act that this type of regulation entails. 27 Gatekeeper<br />

regulation, he argues, is pointless if it impairs information flow to gatekeepers: "Any<br />

improvement in gatekeeper response to risk that comes from these rules has to be<br />

weighed against potential reduction in gatekeeper information and consequent<br />

impairment of gatekeeper evaluation of risk." 2 In order to optimize the regulation<br />

of gatekeepers, he suggests that experimentation with divergent rules-for example,<br />

American and European rules for auditor and lawyer intervention, rather than<br />

convergence of legal rules, will facilitate the learning process."<br />

III. THE CANADIAN SYSTEM<br />

The Canadian model for gatekeeper liability reflects Painter's suggestion for<br />

resisting a convergence of legal rules, as there remains a high degree of divergence in<br />

the nature of the liability for each corporate gatekeeper. In addition, Choi and<br />

others' concerns with an excessively heavy-handed or interventionist liability scheme<br />

have been largely limited in the Canadian context. Rather, relying heavily on selfregulation,<br />

but resisting the contractual and insurance models proposed by Choi and<br />

Cunningham, the Canadian system has attempted to achieve the balance called for<br />

by Coffee.<br />

Under the current Canadian regime, corporate gatekeepers are open to civil<br />

liability, but in practice, investors' ability to impose civil liability on corporate<br />

gatekeepers is quite limited. Both substantive and procedural obstacles limit<br />

common law civil liability. The application of the business judgment rule and a<br />

range of statutory defences, in addition to procedural obstacles, limit statutory<br />

(corporate and securities) civil liability, including the new secondary market civil<br />

liability regime found in Ontario's securities legislation. The rules of professional<br />

conduct provided by gatekeepers' Self-Regulatory Organizations (SROs) or industry<br />

22. Id.<br />

23. Id.<br />

24. <strong>Law</strong>rence A. Cunningham, Choosing Gatekeepers: The Financial <strong>State</strong>ment Insurance Alternative<br />

to Auditor Liability, 52 UCLA L. REv. 413 (2004).<br />

25. Id.<br />

26. Id. at 415.<br />

27. Richard W. Painter, Convergence and Competition in Rules Governing <strong>Law</strong>yers and Auditors, 29<br />

J. CORP. L. 397, 400 (2004).<br />

28. Id. at 407.<br />

29. Id. at 425.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 445 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

bodies either do not provide for or are unlikely to result in liability to third parties.<br />

Taken together, the Canadian approach to civil liability for corporate gatekeepers is<br />

consistent with the U.S. and U.K. models, to the extent that it has been informed by<br />

concerns relating to the promotion of investor confidence in the fairness of the<br />

market. The harm perpetrated against individual investors has been seen as a matter<br />

of secondary importance.<br />

A. Common <strong>Law</strong><br />

A traditional source of civil liability for many gatekeepers, including directors<br />

and auditors, is common law. Under common law, investors are able to bring an<br />

action against directors for a breach of fiduciary duty and duty of care, as well as<br />

seek remedies in contract and tort. However, these causes of action have generally<br />

been supplanted by securities and corporate legislation as the common law remedies<br />

have more onerous substantive and procedural requirements to be met.<br />

In order to bring a common law action forward against a lawyer, investors must<br />

meet the standard set forth in Filipovic v. Upshall, which established that "the<br />

[lawyers] stood in a sufficient relationship of proximity with the plaintiffs to<br />

engender a duty of care on their part . . . . It required the defendants to carry out<br />

their duties as corporate lawyers in a reasonably professional and competent manner<br />

and with the utmost good faith." 3 " In CC&L Dedicated Enterprise Fund v.<br />

Fisherman, the court held that a prima facie duty of care exists when a lawyer makes<br />

representations to the investing public for the purpose of furthering the investments<br />

in their client. " This duty will only be negated through policy considerations if the<br />

factual situation shows no reasonable alternative action by the lawyer that would not<br />

bias the client. The motion also holds that this duty may be breached through a<br />

failure to prevent misrepresentations by the client or failure to withdraw services in<br />

the face of fraudulent activities. However, while CCL and Filipovic do allow the<br />

possibility that a lawyer may be found to owe a fiduciary duty of care to investors, it<br />

is difficult for investors to establish that duty, and once established, the courts are<br />

relatively unlikely to find negligence or breach of duty of care giving rise to<br />

damages. 32<br />

Against auditors, there is the possibility of relief for shareholders in tort, as the<br />

Supreme Court of Canada held in Hercules that it is reasonable for a corporation's<br />

shareholders to make investment decisions relying on the correctness of the<br />

corporation's audited financial statements. 33 However, that decision largely curtailed<br />

the potential scope of liability under the second stage of the Anns/Kamloops test,<br />

which addresses policy considerations. 34 The primary concern is that the defendant<br />

might be exposed to indeterminate liability from an indeterminate class, and in<br />

Hercules the Court held that a duty of care for negligence only arises when the<br />

claimants are known to the defendant as a clearly defined class, and that their usage<br />

of the representation is for the primary purpose for which the representation was<br />

30. Filipovic v. Upshall, No. 2256, 1998 O.J.<br />

31. C.C.&L. Dedicated Enterprise Fund v. Fisherman, 18 B.L.R. (3d) 240 (Ont. Sup. Ct. J. 2001).<br />

32. Dupuis v. Pan American Mines, 7 B.L.R. 288 (Que. S.C. 1979).<br />

33. Hercules Management Ltd. v. Ernst & Young, 2 S.C.R. 165 (1997) (Can.).<br />

34. Id. at paras. 44-46.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 446 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

created. 35 In that case, it was held that the corporations' auditors did not have a duty<br />

of care to the shareholders and investors. 6 Beyond tort, shareholders cannot sue<br />

auditors under contracts, because the courts have consistently held that auditors<br />

enter into a contract with a corporation and not its shareholders .<br />

In contrast, a common law action for negligent misrepresentation by the<br />

investment advisor may be possible, as an investment advisor will likely be found to<br />

owe a duty of care to the investor through application of the Anns/Kamloops test.<br />

The investment advisor's relationship with the client generally indicates a provision<br />

of professional services in accordance with industry practice and standards. 8 There<br />

may also be a contractual relationship between the client and the investment advisor,<br />

with any claim of liability dependent on the written and unwritten terms of such a<br />

contract. As well, since the investment advisor's relationship with his or her client is<br />

one of agency, the investment advisor owes a fiduciary duty to the client.<br />

Accordingly, to the extent that investment advisors are required by their fiduciary<br />

relationship, their contracts, and industry practise and standards to suggest and sell<br />

suitable products to their clients, those advisors may also be performing a<br />

gatekeeping function. However, the case law does not suggest that this is the focus<br />

of litigation in this area."<br />

The other three categories of gatekeepers-underwriters, credit reporting<br />

agencies, and financial analysts-are even less likely to be held liable under common<br />

law. For underwriters, common law is largely irrelevant; their primary source of civil<br />

liability is statutory. Like auditors, credit reporting agencies also use the second<br />

stage of the Anns/Kamloops test to avoid liability to shareholders in tort actions.<br />

Finally, financial analysts can sometimes be liable for negligent misrepresentation,<br />

40<br />

but that type of action is only likely to be pursued in very extreme cases.<br />

35. Id. at para. 46; see also Bow Valley Huskey (Bermuda) Ltd. v. Saint John Shipbuilding Ltd., 3<br />

S.C.R. 1210, para. 62 (1997).<br />

36. Although Hercules limits the common law right against auditors for negligent misrepresentation,<br />

this limit only reaches so far. In Kripps v. Touche Ross, 6 W.W.R. 421 (1997), 33 B.C.L.R. (3d) 254 (C.A.)<br />

(leave to appeal refused 225 N.R. 236n (S.C.C. 1997)) (note: although Kripps was decided before the<br />

Hercules case, leave to appeal was denied after Hercules), investors who purchased debentures issued by a<br />

mortgage company that went bankrupt sued the auditors. The investors claimed the auditor's report was a<br />

negligent misrepresentation since the financial statements had not accurately reflected the company's<br />

financial position. The plaintiff investors argued that they had relied on the auditor's report and the<br />

auditors should have been aware that the investors would rely on the auditor's certification that the<br />

mortgage company's financial statements were accurate. Unlike in Hercules, the British Columbia Court of<br />

Appeal held that the auditor was liable. Although the auditors complied with applicable accounting and<br />

auditing rules, they allowed the company to understate its losses in a fashion that could mislead investors.<br />

At the time of the events in Kripps, there was no statutory civil liability for auditors under the Britsh<br />

Columbia Securities Act. In contrast, in Hercules, since financial statements were only part of the<br />

company's annual financial disclosure then, for policy reasons, the auditors were not held liable for<br />

negligent misrepresentation.<br />

37. See Hercules, supra note 33. Roman Corp. Ltd. v. Peat Marwick Thorne., 11 O.R. 3d 248 [1992].<br />

38. Gowlings Lafleur Henderson LLP, INVESTMENT ADVISORS' LIABILITY (2001),<br />

http://www.gowlings.com/resources/publicationpdfs/InvestmentAdvisorsLiability.pdf (last visited Feb. 20,<br />

2007).<br />

39. Id. The Gowlings memorandum provides an excellent overview of the case law in this area.<br />

40. Securities Industry Committee on Analyst Standards, Setting Analyst Standards:<br />

Recommendations for the Supervision and Practice of Canadian Securities Industry Analysts (2001), 38<br />

(SICAS Report).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 447 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

B. Statutory Liability<br />

i. Corporate Statutes<br />

The gatekeepers most heavily regulated by statute are directors. They owe a<br />

fiduciary duty to the corporation under section 122(1)(a) of the Canada Business<br />

Corporations Act (CBCA) (and the equivalent sections of the provincial acts) to<br />

"act honestly and in good faith with a view to the best interests of the corporation." 1<br />

If they breach that fiduciary duty to the detriment of the company, stakeholders can<br />

bring forward a suit using section 239 of the CBCA, which allows derivative actions<br />

by complainants on behalf of the corporation." Section 238 of the CBCA defines<br />

complainants and includes "any other person who, in the discretion of a court, is a<br />

proper person to make an application under this Part." 43 However, in the recent case<br />

of Peoples Department Stores Inc. v. Wise, the Supreme Court of Canada held that<br />

the fiduciary duty of directors does not extend beyond the corporation directly to its<br />

creditors." The Court stated that "in determining whether [directors] are acting with<br />

a view to the best interests of the corporation it may be legitimate, given all the<br />

circumstances of a given case, for the board of directors to consider, among other<br />

things, the interests of shareholders, employees, suppliers, creditors, consumers,<br />

governments and the environment.""<br />

Thus, one argument available to directors is that they were balancing multiple<br />

interests, or acting in "the best interests of the corporation" in the discharge of their<br />

fiduciary duty. 46 Directors can also use other principles including the "business<br />

judgment rule" to help defend against allegations of breach of duty." The business<br />

judgment rule holds that directors are not obliged to give continuous attention to the<br />

company's affairs but their duties are awakened when information and events that<br />

require further investigation become known to them. 48 This rule is utilized by the<br />

judiciary to "protect[] Boards and directors from those that might second-guess their<br />

41. Business Corporations Act, R.S.C, ch. C-44 (1985) [hereinafter CBCA]; see also Business<br />

Corporations Act, R.S.O., ch. B.16, § 134 (1990) [hereinafter OBCA]; Business Corporations Act,<br />

R.S.B.C., ch. 57, § 142 (2002) [hereinafter BCBCA]; Business Corporations Act, R.S.A., ch. B-9, § 122<br />

(2000) [hereinafter ABCA]; Corporations Act, C.C.S.M. ch. C-225, § 117 [hereinafter MCA]; Business<br />

Corporations Act, R.S.S., ch. B-10, § 117 (1978) [hereinafter SBCAJ; Business Corporations Act, S.N.B.,<br />

ch. B-9.1, § 79 (1981) [hereinafter NBBCA]; Corporations Act, R.S.N.L., ch. C-36, § 203 (1990) [hereinafter<br />

NFCA]; Business Corporations Act, R.S.Y., ch. 20, § 124 (2002) [hereinafter YBCA]; Business<br />

Corporations Act, S.N.W.T., ch. 19, § 123 (1996) [hereinafter NW'TBCA].<br />

42. CBCA, supra note 41; see also OBCA, supra note 41, § 246; BCBCA, supra note 41, § 232; ABCA,<br />

supra note 41, § 240; MCA, supra note 41, § 232; SBCA, supra note 41, § 232; NBBCA, supra note 41, §<br />

164; NFCA, supra note 41, § 369; YBCA, supra note 41, § 241; NWTBCA, supra note 41, § 241; and<br />

Companies Act, R.S.N.S., ch. 81 Third Schedule, § 4 (1989) [hereinafter NSCA].<br />

43. CBCA, supra note 41; see also OBCA, supra note 41, § 245; BCBCA, supra note 41, § 232; ABCA,<br />

supra note 41, § 239; MCA, supra note 41, § 231; SBCA, supra note 41, § 231; NBBCA, supra note 41, §<br />

163; NFCA, supra note 41, § 368; YBCA, supra note 41, § 240; NWTBCA, supra note 41, § 240; NSCA,<br />

supra note 41, Third Schedule, § 1.<br />

44. Peoples Dep't Stores, Inc. v. Wise, [2004] 3 S.C.R. 461, para. 43.<br />

45. Id. para. 42.<br />

46. UPM-Kymmene Corp. v. UPM-Kymmene Miramichi, Inc. No. 2412, [2002] 214 B.L.R. 496, 528,<br />

para. 117.<br />

47. Id. paras. 152-56.<br />

48. Id. para. 126.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 448 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

• . . business decisions." 9 To apply the rule, the courts must find that the directors<br />

were "scrupulous in their deliberations and demonstrate diligence in arriving at<br />

decisions." 5<br />

The other major defence available to directors is that of due diligence or good<br />

faith reliance. Directors can be relieved of any liability if they relied in good faith on<br />

financial statements produced by an officer or auditor of the corporation or a report<br />

of a professional. A number of provinces offer directors both a good faith reliance<br />

and due diligence defence similar to section 123(4) of the CBCA. 5 These defences<br />

have meant that, in practice, the application of the statutory duty of care has been<br />

extremely limited.<br />

Individual investors can move beyond the statutes mentioned above, and seek<br />

to use the oppression remedy against directors who have failed in their gatekeeping<br />

role. 2 Using that statutory remedy contained in the CBCA and most provincial<br />

statutes, a "complainant" may apply to the court for relief if the business of the<br />

corporation or the powers of the directors have been exercised in a manner that is<br />

"oppressive or unfairly prejudicial to or that unfairly disregards the interests" of any<br />

security holder, creditor, director or officer. 53 In Peoples, the Court's reasoning<br />

suggests that in future cases the oppression remedy analysis will not require a<br />

determination of whether directors have breached their fiduciary duties and that it<br />

may be possible to use the oppression remedy to hold directors accountable to<br />

individual stakeholders. " However, neither position is new and the above statement<br />

can be taken as obiter as the case itself did not concern an oppression action. 5 This<br />

highlights one of the difficulties in assessing the oppression remedy, as there are<br />

relatively few oppression actions in the courts each year. As a result, the judicial<br />

treatment of the oppression remedy has frequently drawn from the case law on<br />

breach of statutory duties, importing concepts such as the "best interests of the<br />

corporation" and the "business judgment rule." 56 The notion that a director's<br />

49. Id. para. 152.<br />

50. Id. para. 153.<br />

51. ABCA, supra note 41, § 123(3); see also YBCA, supra note 41, s. 125(3); NWTBCA, supra note<br />

41, § 124(3).<br />

52. See Peoples, 3 S.C.R. 461, para 48.<br />

53. CBCA, supra note 41, § 241(1) and (2); OBCA, supra note 41, § 248; ABCA, supra note 41, § 242;<br />

SBCA, supra note 41, § 234; MCA, supra note 41, § 207; NBIBCA, supra note 41, § 166; NSCA, supra note<br />

42, Third Schedule, § 5; NFCA, supra note 41, § 371; YBCA, supra note 41, § 243; and NWTBCA, supra<br />

note 41, § 243. Under the CBCA, supra note 41, § 238, a complainant is defined as a registered holder or<br />

beneficial holder of a security (or a former registered holder or beneficial holder) of a corporation or any<br />

of its affiliates, a director or an officer of a corporation or any of its affiliates (or a former director/officer),<br />

the Director (appointed under § 260 of the act), or any other person deemed a "proper person" by the<br />

court.<br />

54. Peoples, 3 S.C.R. 461, para. 53.<br />

55. Rather, the case was based on the issue of whether directors owe a duty to creditors. The trustee,<br />

representing the interests of the creditors, sued the directors for an alleged breach of the duties imposed by<br />

§ 122(1) of the CBCA. In its analysis, the Court recognized that, according to article 300 of the Q.C.C. and<br />

§ 8.1 of the Interpretation Act, R.S.C., ch. 1-21 (1985), the civil law serves as a supplementary source of law<br />

to federal legislation. The CBCA does not entitle creditors to sue directors directly for breach of their<br />

duties, and so the Court deemed it appropriate to have recourse to the Q.C.C. to establish how rights<br />

grounded in a federal statute should be considered in Quebec. The Court also looked to the Q.C.C. to<br />

determine how § 122(1) of the CBCA can be harmonized with the principles of civil liability. See Peoples,<br />

3 S.C.R. 461, paras. 29-30.<br />

56. Peoples, 3 S.C.R. 461, para. 64.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 449 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

fiduciary duty includes an obligation to balance a number of interests has also been<br />

considered by courts applying the oppression remedy, as in Re Ferguson and Imax<br />

Systems Corp., 7 wherein the Court of Appeal for Ontario held that it was imperative<br />

that the oppression remedy be applied in a manner that balances the protection of<br />

stakeholders and the ability of management to conduct business in an efficient<br />

manner.<br />

ii.<br />

Securities Statutes<br />

While directors are the primary gatekeepers regulated under the CBCA, all<br />

corporate gatekeepers are, to some degree, subject to securities statutes. The<br />

statutes differ from province to province, but here, the discussion will focus on the<br />

Ontario Securities Act (OSA). While many of its provisions are similar to those of<br />

other provinces, Ontario is noteworthy as it is the only province to impose secondary<br />

market liability on some corporate gatekeepers."<br />

Under securities legislation, directors may be liable to persons who acquire<br />

securities in a corporation during the period of distribution while there are<br />

uncorrected misrepresentations in a prospectus." The purchaser need not show<br />

reliance on the misrepresentation for liability to attach. 6 The onus shifts to the<br />

defendant to show that any depreciation in the value of the securities was not the<br />

result of the misrepresentation. 61 The plaintiff has no claim if he or she knew of the<br />

57. 43 O.R. 2d 128, 137 (C.A. 1983). This was an appeal after the application for relief was dismissed<br />

under s. 234 of the Canada Business Corporations Act. S.C., c. 33 (1974-5). The appellant claimed that the<br />

corporation and the directors had, by organizing a special meeting to vote on a resolution to amend its<br />

articles to reorganize its capital, acted in a manner that was oppressive, unfairly prejudicial, or unfairly<br />

disregarded her interests as a security holder. On appeal, Brooke J.A. found for the appellant and granted<br />

her relief for oppression.<br />

58. British Columbia has proposed legislation (Bill 38) implementing a similar regime, but the<br />

implementation of this legislation has been put on hold. See BC Securities Commission,<br />

http://www.bcsc.bc.ca/instruments.asp?id=1894#moving and http://www.bcsc.bc.ca/release.asp?id=2944 for<br />

details.<br />

59. Securities Act, R.S.O., ch. S-5, § 58 (1990) [hereinafter OSA]; Securities Act, R.S.B.C., ch. 418, §<br />

68 (1996) [hereinafter BCSAJ: Securities Act, R.S.A., ch. S-4, § 116 (2000) [hereinafter ASA]; Securities<br />

Act, C.C.S.M. ch. S-50, § 52(1) [hereinafter MSA] (requires certification by the directors that a prospectus<br />

contains "full true and plain disclosure"); Securities Act, R.S.Y., ch. 201, § 22 (2002) [hereinafter YSA]<br />

(requires only the signing of the prospectus by the directors with no specific certification); see also<br />

Securities Act, R.S.Q., ch. V-I.1, § 220 [hereinafter QSA]; Securities Act, 1988, S.S., ch. S-42.2, § 66 (1988-<br />

89) [hereinafter SSA]; Securities Act, S.N.B., ch. S-5.5, §74(3) (2004) [hereinafter NBSA]: Securities Act,<br />

R.S.N.S., ch. 418, § 63 (1989) [hereinafter NSSAI; Securities Act, R.S.P.E.I., ch. S-3, § 8.5 (1988)<br />

[hereinafter PEISA]; Securities Act, R.S.N.L., ch. S-13, § 59 (1990) [hereinafter NLSA]; but see Securities<br />

Act, R.S.N.W.T., ch. S-5 (1988) [hereinafter NWTSA], which does not mention certification by directors.<br />

60. OSA, supra note 59, § 130(1); BCSA, supra note 59, § 131(1)(a); ASA, supra note 59, § 203(1);<br />

SSA, supra note 59, § 137(1); NBSA, supra note 59, § 149(1); NSSA, supra note 59, § 137(1); PEISA, supra<br />

note 59, § 16(1); NLSA, supra note 59, § 130(1); but see QSA, supra note 59, §§ 217-219 (where there is no<br />

specific reference to deemed reliance, although non-reliance is not a listed defence under § 217 or § 220);<br />

MSA, supra note 59. This act makes no specific reference to deemed reliance, although non-reliance is not<br />

a listed defence under § 65. The right to rescission under § 65 applies only to the issuer. See also NWTSA<br />

and YSA, supra note 59 (Under these acts, like the MSA, the right to rescission applies only against the<br />

issuer and there is no specific mention of deemed reliance).<br />

61. ASA, supra note 59, § 203(9); BCSA, supra note 59, § 131(10); OSA, supra note 59, § 130(7); SSA,<br />

supra note 59, § 137(8); NBSA, supra note 59, § 149(8); NSSA, supra note 59, § 137(7); PEISA, supra note<br />

59. § 16(7); NLSA, supra note 59, § 130(7).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 450 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

representation. 62 Directors, along with the issuer, underwriter, an expert who has<br />

filed a consent, and anyone else who has signed the prospectus, are jointly and<br />

severally liable.<br />

Liability for a prospectus misrepresentation is generally only alleviated if the<br />

prospectus was filed without the director's consent, the director withdrew consent<br />

within a reasonable period of time upon discovery of a misrepresentation, or the<br />

director exercised due diligence but failed to ascertain the existence of the<br />

misrepresentation (other defences are not relevant to the gatekeeping function). 6<br />

Most recently, in Kerr v. Danier Leather Inc.,6' the first class action to be litigated to<br />

the final stages by shareholders for a prospectus misrepresentation under section 130<br />

of the OSA, the Court of Appeal for Ontario used the business judgment rule to<br />

protect directors from personal liability. The decision suggests that the business<br />

judgment rule will serve as an important shield for directors in future litigation using<br />

the statutory liability provisions for misrepresentation found in the provincial<br />

securities acts, including the new secondary market civil liability regime in Ontario<br />

discussed below. The liability for initial disclosure documents in general does not<br />

appear to be consistent across Canada, though generally, the scope of damages for a<br />

misrepresentation in the primary markets is limited to the price at which the<br />

securities were offered to the public. 65 Quebec, which does not appear to have a<br />

specific clause limiting damages, is the exception.'<br />

The Ontario Securities Commission (OSC) is also limited in its authority to deal<br />

with lawyers. While it can exercise some control over lawyers practicing within its<br />

area of jurisdiction, according to the Court of Appeal for Ontario, solicitor-client<br />

privilege must be maintained. 67 It must be noted that the power of the securities<br />

commissions to sanction and reprimand lawyers does not necessarily extend to the<br />

ability to place remedial sanctions limiting lawyers' ability to practice in the<br />

securities area in the future; this would bring the commission into the role of<br />

regulating the practice of law, an area reserved for the law societies. 6 " Still, section<br />

130(1) of the OSA applies to lawyers, including their statements in a category of<br />

"expert" opinions to which liability may be attributed for misrepresentations. 69 A<br />

misrepresentation that triggers this section will create joint and several liability with<br />

any other party listed in section 130(1)." 0 The defenses for experts like lawyers,<br />

auditors, and other gatekeepers discussed below include: filing of the prospectus<br />

without consent, withdrawal of consent upon discovery of a misrepresentation,<br />

62. ASA, supra note 59, § 203(4): BCSA, supra note 59, § 131(4); OSA, supra note 59, § 130(2); SSA,<br />

supra note 59, § 137(3); NBSA, supra note 59, § 149(3); NSSA, supra note 59, § 137(2); PEISA, supra note<br />

59, § 16(2); NLSA, supra note 59, § 130(2).<br />

63. See MSA, supra note 59, § 97.<br />

64. Kerr v. Danier Leather Inc., [2005] O.J. No. 5388; [2005] LEXIS 6560.[Ruth, the only version we<br />

are able to get is the LEXIS version because Tarlton stopped getting the printed cases, Andy].<br />

65. OSA, supra note 59, § 130(9); BCSA, supra note 59, § 131(13); ASA, supra note 59, § 203(13);<br />

SSA, supra note 59, § 138(11); NBSA, supra note 59, § 149(11); NSSA, supra note 59, § 137(9); PEISA,<br />

supra note 59, § 16(9); NFSA, supra note 59, § 130(9). NWT, Yukon, and Manitoba appear to only provide<br />

a right of rescission, which would preclude a need to limit damages to the price at offering.<br />

66. RSQ, supra note 60 § 214 (discussing damages, but not indicating any limitations).<br />

67. Wilder v. Ontario Sec. Comm'n, [20011 53 O.R. (3d) 519 (C.A.).<br />

68. See Henderson v. Alberta Sec. Comm'n, [2002] ABCA 264 (Alta. C.A.) and Ainsley Fin. Corp. v.<br />

Ontario Sec. Comm'n, [1994] 21 O.R. (3d) 104 (Ont. C.A.).<br />

69. OSA, supra note 60, §130(1).<br />

70. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 451 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

notification of the securities commission and the public of the misrepresentation, and<br />

due diligence. 71<br />

Auditors are also covered under section 130(1) of the OSA as experts, and thus<br />

securities statutes are a source of liability for them.' However, because the Supreme<br />

Court of Canada in Hercules-found that auditors owe a duty of care to corporations<br />

and not shareholders, for shareholders to bring an action using a corporate statute<br />

against an auditor, they would need to use the derivative action discussed above in<br />

the context of directors. 7 Another similarity between auditors and directors is that<br />

the oppression remedy may possibly be used against auditors though it is far more<br />

limited in that context, as an attempt to use oppression action in Ontario was<br />

rejected because it is the "corporation or any of its affiliates" that must have acted<br />

oppressively and auditors were found to fall outside of this realm.<br />

Securities statutes provide a source of liability for underwriters as well as<br />

lawyers and directors. The OSA requires underwriters to provide a signed<br />

certificate for inclusion with the prospectus with respect to the securities offered by<br />

the prospectus that:<br />

[T]o the best of their knowledge, information and belief, the foregoing<br />

constitutes full, true and plain disclosure of all material facts relating to the<br />

securities offered by this prospectus as required by Part XV of the<br />

Securities Act and the regulations there under. 75<br />

Underwriters who certify the prospectus are exposed to statutory civil liability<br />

to any purchaser for damages or rescission where such purchaser buys a security<br />

offered pursuant to a prospectus during the distribution period." However, where<br />

an underwriter is a defendant, the underwriter's maximum liability is generally the<br />

portion of the distribution underwritten by the underwriter (this limitation of<br />

liability does not exist in Quebec).7<br />

Credit rating agencies, financial analysts and retail investment advisors are all<br />

subject to section 130(1) of the OSA. However, as section 130 applies to civil<br />

liability for misrepresentation, these groups would only be included as possible<br />

defendants under paragraph (d) if their consent had been filed pursuant to a<br />

requirement of the regulation with respect to reports, opinions, or statements that<br />

had been made by them, or, under paragraph (e), if the CRA actually signed the<br />

prospectus or amendment to the prospectus. 78 The scope of civil liability stemming<br />

from securities statutes is smaller for these gatekeepers than the liability of those<br />

discussed above.<br />

71. OSA, supra note 59, §§ 138.5(3), 138.4(11), 138.4(14), 138.4(6), 138.4(9).<br />

72. Id. § 130(1).<br />

73. Hercules, supra note 33, at 171-72.<br />

74. Budd v. Gentra, B102/95, [1996] O.J. 3515 QUICKLAW (Gen. Div.), [19961 12 O.T.C. 117, aff'd<br />

[1998] 43 B..R. (3d) 27 (Ont. C.A.). In the appeal decision, the oppression claim against the officers and<br />

directors was also struck because it contained no allegation of specific acts they had done.<br />

75. OSA, supra note 59, § 59(1); see also BCSA, supra note 47, § 69; ASA, supra note 59, § 117; MSA<br />

supra note 59, § 53; SSA, supra note 59, § 67; QSA, supra note 59, § 33.2; NBSA, supra note 59, § 74(3);<br />

NSSA, supra note 59, § 64; PEISA, supra note 59, § 8.6; NLSA, supra note 59, § 60.<br />

76. OSA, supra note 60, §§ 59 and 130(1)(b); see also QSA, supra note 59.<br />

77. Id.<br />

78. Id. § 130(1).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 452 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

iii.<br />

Secondary Market Liability<br />

Pearson v. Boliden Ltd. 9 confirms that to take advantage of the above statutory<br />

provisions creating civil liability for primary market misrepresentations, the<br />

purchaser must have purchased the securities directly from the issuer rather than in<br />

the secondary market. However, in Ontario, the recent proclamation of the<br />

"Keeping the Promise for a Strong Economy Act" which went into effect on<br />

December 31, 2005, has introduced a statutory regime of civil liability for secondary<br />

market disclosures through the introduction of part XXIII.1 to the OSA., The<br />

amendments extend the civil liability regime beyond primary market disclosures, and<br />

they apply to all Ontario reporting issuers and to any company with publicly traded<br />

securities that has a real and substantial connection to Ontario. The amendments<br />

also open the door for class action lawsuits that allege misrepresentations by creating<br />

a statutory right of action without regard to whether the purchaser or seller of<br />

securities relied on the alleged misrepresentation or delay in disclosure. Improper<br />

continuous disclosure can include a misrepresentation in a document or other<br />

communication, which would reasonably be expected to affect the share price, or a<br />

failure to make timely disclosure of material changes."<br />

It is important to note that in order to proceed with an action for damages<br />

under the new secondary market liability scheme, an investor must obtain leave of<br />

the court." Each defendant must receive notice of the motion for leave to proceed. 83<br />

The court will grant leave only if it is satisfied that the investor is bringing the action<br />

in good faith, and there is a reasonable possibility that the action will be resolved at<br />

trial in favour of the investor." The plaintiff must have bought the securities while<br />

the misrepresentation was uncorrected and without knowledge of the<br />

misrepresentation, but need not show reliance on the misrepresentation. 85<br />

Directors can defend themselves with any of the following arguments: (1) the<br />

change in the value of the securities is not related to the misrepresentation (onus on<br />

defendant to show);6 (2) the defendant relied on an expert report; 8 7 (3) the<br />

defendant relied on another publicly filed report;m (4) the defendant conducted a<br />

reasonable investigation, or, for a failure to make timely disclosure, if the defendant<br />

can prove he did not know of the change; 9 and (5) an exemption on<br />

misrepresentation of "forward-looking" information, provided that the document or<br />

public oral statement contains cautionary language relating to the forward-looking<br />

79. Pearson v. Boliden Ltd. [2002] BCCA 624, 7 B.C.L.R. (4th) 245 (B.C.C.A.), 2002 BCCA 624.<br />

80. Keeping the Promise for a Strong Economy Act (Budget Measures), 2002, S.O. 2002, cls. 182-83.<br />

81. OSA, supra note 59, § 138.3. The distinction between "material fact" and "material change," also<br />

found in § 130 of the OSA (and defined in § 1 of the OSA), was critical to the appellate ruling in Kerr v.<br />

Danier, supra note 64, where the court confirmed that "material fact" is intended to be defined more<br />

broadly than "material change" in the Act. The Court of Appeal agreed with the trial court that the impact<br />

of unseasonably warm weather did not constitute a "material change" in Danier's business or operations.<br />

82. OSA, supra note 60, § 138.8(1).<br />

83. Id. § 138.8(1)(a)-(b).<br />

84. Id. § 138.8(1).<br />

85. Id. §138.4(7)(f).<br />

86. Id. § 138.5(3).<br />

87. Id. § 138.4(11).<br />

88. OSA, supra note 60, § 138.4(14).<br />

89. Id. § 138.4(6).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 453 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

information, identifies material factors that could cause actual results to differ<br />

materially, and states the material factors or assumptions that were applied in<br />

making a forecast or projection in the forward-looking information.' There is also a<br />

whistleblowing defence available if the following criteria are satisfied: the<br />

contravention was made without that defendant's knowledge or consent; upon<br />

becoming aware of the misrepresentation the defendant promptly notified the board<br />

of directors of the issuer of the matter, and. if no correction or subsequent disclosure<br />

was made, the defendant promptly provided the Ontario Securities Commission<br />

(OSC) with written notification of the misrepresentation. 9 '<br />

Secondary market liability also applies to lawyers, auditors and financial<br />

analysts as experts under section 138.1 of the OSA if their report, contains<br />

misrepresentations used in a public statement (written or oral).' An investor can<br />

sue an "expert" if the misrepresentation is also contained in a report, statement or<br />

opinion made by the expert (Expert Report); if the document or statement includes,<br />

summarizes or quotes from the Expert Report; and the expert consented in writing<br />

to the use of the Expert Report in a document released or statement made by<br />

someone other than the expert. 93 Experts are able to use the same defences as<br />

directors, listed above, and their liability is limited to the greater of $1 million or the<br />

amount of revenue raised from the responsible issuer within the last 12 months. 9<br />

Unlike the other groups of gatekeepers, underwriters are not included in section<br />

138.3(1), and credit rating agencies are explicitly excluded from secondary market<br />

liability in section 138.1(1) of the OSA. It is not immediately clear from the<br />

legislation if retail investment advisors are included under this section.<br />

Because secondary market liability is quite new to Ontario, there has been little<br />

jurisprudence, so it is unclear how much protection these defences will afford<br />

directors and other gatekeepers, and how much success shareholders will have in<br />

holding failed gatekeepers liable.<br />

C. Other Regulatory Regimes<br />

i. Provincial Securities Commissions<br />

Provincial securities commissions have broad powers to enforce securities laws<br />

through the imposition of administrative orders in the public interest. Included<br />

among the long list of possible administrative sanctions is the ability of commissions<br />

to impose a penalty, if it is determined at the hearing that a person or company has<br />

contravened-or failed to comply with-any provision of the securities legislation. 95<br />

90. Id. § 138.4(9).<br />

91. Id. § 138.4(15).<br />

92. Id. § 138.3.<br />

93. Id. § 138.4(12).<br />

94. OSA, supra note 60,. § 138.1.<br />

95. Id. § 127(1)10 (imposing a penalty of up to $1 million); BCSA, supra note 59, § 162 (up to $250,000<br />

for individuals and $500,000 for persons who are not individuals); ASA, supra note 59, § 199 (up to $1<br />

million); MSA, supra note 59, § 148 (up to $100,000 for an individual and $500,000 for persons who are not<br />

individuals); SSA, supra note 59, § 135 (up to $100,000); QSA, supra note 59, §273 (up to $1 million);<br />

NBSA, supra note 59, § 186 (up to $750,000); NSSA, supra note 59, § 135 (up to $100,000).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 454 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

In addition, the securities commissions can apply to the court for a declaration<br />

that a person or company has not complied with a provision of the securities act. 6<br />

On application by a commission, the court may make an order imposing a penalty or<br />

requiring current directors or officers to be removed and replaced, requiring a<br />

person or company to compensate or make restitution to an aggrieved person or<br />

company, requiring a person or company to pay general or punitive damages, or<br />

requiring a person or company to pay the Provincial Treasurer any amounts<br />

obtained as a result of non-compliance with any provision of the securities act. 97<br />

These judicial and administrative sanctions apply to all of the corporate gatekeepers<br />

under consideration.<br />

For directors specifically, the OSC can seek administrative sanctions if the<br />

financial information contained in the company's press release was materially<br />

misleading and that the directors therefore acted contrary to the public interest by<br />

not making sufficient inquiries before releasing the interim financial results, as in<br />

Standard Trustco Ltd. 98 In that case, the OSC criticized the directors for<br />

inappropriately approving financial statements and disseminating the information<br />

publicly. It also noted that directors who are members of the audit committee<br />

should bear more responsibility than other directors for a compliance deficiency in<br />

the corporation's financial statements. 99<br />

The securities commissions do not appear to have successfully extended liability<br />

to lawyers acting merely in their role as gatekeeper: something more is required for<br />

liability to attach. For example, in Re Orsini, a lawyer prepared a financing scheme<br />

that breached various provisions of the OSA; the lawyer was involved directly in<br />

developing the scheme, and benefited materially from the sale of shares."' In<br />

contrast, Henderson v. Alberta (Securities Commission) involved a situation where a<br />

lawyer had met with potential investors and did not deliver them the required<br />

documentation; despite the initial finding of the trial court against the lawyer, the<br />

Alberta Court of Appeal held that he had made his dealings in good faith, and<br />

reversed the trial judgment. 01 These two cases suggest that innocent-though<br />

nonetheless negligent-failure to prevent a client from committing a violation of<br />

securities law does not create a violation giving rise to administrative sanctions<br />

against lawyers. Sanctions will not be imposed unless the lawyer personally<br />

performed an action which triggers an offence.<br />

Underwriters are treated somewhat uniquely by provincial securities<br />

commissions, as their role is to be not only a gatekeeper but also a devil's advocate,<br />

as per the OSC's regulatory proceeding, YBM Magnex International Inc. (Re). l "' In<br />

96. OSA, supra note 59, § 128; BCSA, supra note 59, § 157; ASA, supra note 59, § 197; MSA, supra<br />

note 59, § 152; SSA, supra note 59, § 133; NBSA, supra note 59, § 187; NSSA, supra note 59, § 133; NFSA,<br />

supra note 59, § 128.1.<br />

97. OSA, supra note 59; BCSA, supra note 59; ASA, supra note 59; MSA, supra note 59; SSA, supra<br />

note 59; NBSA, supra note 59; NSSA, supra note 59; NFSA, supra note 59; see also QSA, supra note 59 §<br />

269.2 (the QSA specifies only damages as possible remedies); PEISA, supra note 59, § 19; YSA, supra note<br />

59, § 19; NWTSA, supra note 59, § 22.<br />

98. Re Standard Trustco Ltd., [1992] 6 B.L.R. (2d) 241,244; 15 O.S.C. Bull. 4322 (Ont. Can.).<br />

99. Id. at 245.<br />

100. Re Orsini, [1991] 2 B.L.R. (2d) 271, 14 O.S.C.B. 4820 (Ont. Can.).<br />

101. Henderson v. Alberta, [20021 ABCA 264 (Alta. C.A.).<br />

102. Re YBM Magnex Int'l, [2003] 26 O.S.C. Bull. 5285, paras. 187-99 (Ont. Can.).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 455 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

Re A.E. Ames & Co. Ltd, the OSC held that as gatekeeper, there is a duty upon the<br />

underwriter to uncover all the facts.' 7 While in Feit v. Leasco Data Processing<br />

Equipment Corp. the OSC recognized limits of the underwriter's role because of<br />

more limited access to information, as devil's advocates, underwriters must challenge<br />

the issuer's disclosure with respect to any misconduct, otherwise they may be subject<br />

to administrative sanctions in addition to civil liability as discussed above"<br />

Underwriters, financial analysts, and retail investment advisors must all register<br />

under provincial securities legislation, as firms that engage in securities underwriting,<br />

investment firms, and all securities firms and their employees who provide trading<br />

and advising services, respectively' 5 As a result of the mandatory registration<br />

requirement, the provincial securities commissions have the power to suspend or<br />

revoke the registration of a wayward registrant,'06 which may include situations<br />

where the firm fails to properly supervise the analysts (employees) at the firm.<br />

ii.<br />

Market Regulation Services Inc.<br />

Market Regulation Services Inc. (RS) is a SRO recognized by the securities<br />

commissions in Alberta, British Columbia, Manitoba, Ontario and Quebec as a<br />

market regulation provider for the trade exchanges and trading systems in Canada.' 7<br />

RS administers the Universal Market Integrity Rules (UMIR), which apply to<br />

directors and lawyers as corporate gatekeepers. 10.16 of UMIR provides a set of<br />

reporting obligations for directors as gatekeepers of market participants.' Directors<br />

of market participants are obligated to report trading violations to the compliance<br />

department of the participant. Section 10.3 of UMIR allows for a finding of liability<br />

for a market participant through the actions of their directors, officers, partners, or<br />

employees." 9 Similarly, a director or partner may be found liable for the actions of<br />

the firm and face personal sanctions, while a lawyer hired by a market participant<br />

can be liable under this section as the employee of a market participant.<br />

Section 10.5 of UMIR provides a broad power to the market regulator to<br />

impose sanctions for violations of UMIR."" Sanctions include a reprimand, a fine of<br />

up to one million dollars or the amount equal to triple the financial benefit which<br />

accrued to the person as a result of committing the violation, or any other remedy<br />

deemed appropriate under the circumstances. "'<br />

103. Re A.E. Ames & Co. Ltd., [1972] 3 OR. 405 (Ont. C.A.).<br />

104. Feit v. Leasco Data Processing Equip. Corp., 322 F. Supp. 544, 582 (E.D.N.Y. 1971).<br />

105. OSA, supra note 59, § 25(1); BCSA, supra note 59, § 34; ASA, supra note 59, § 75; MSA, supra<br />

note 59, § 6; SSA, supra note 59, § 27; QSA, supra note 59, § 148; NBSA, supra note 59, § 45; NSSA, supra<br />

note 59, § 31; PEISA, supra note 59, § 2; NLSA, supra note 59, § 26; YSA, supra note 59, § 3; NWTSA,<br />

supra note 59, § 4.<br />

106. OSA, supra note 59, § 25(1); BCSA, supra note 59, § 34; ASA, supra note 59, § 75; MSA, supra<br />

note 59, § 6; SSA, supra note 59, § 27; QSA, supra note 59, § 148; NBSA, supra note 59, § 45; NSSA, supra<br />

note 59, § 31; PEISA, supra note 59, § 2; NLSA, supra note 59, § 26; YSA, supra note 59, § 3; NWTSA,<br />

supra note 59, § 4.<br />

107. See Market Regulator, Universal Market Integrity Rules [hereinafter UMIR]<br />

http://www.rs.ca/en/pdfIUMIR.pdf.<br />

108. UMIR §10.16.<br />

109. Id. §10.3.<br />

110. Id. §10.5.<br />

111. Id. §10.5(1).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 456 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

iii.<br />

Professional Regulatory Bodies<br />

Beyond the common sources of liability discussed above, many corporate<br />

gatekeepers are also regulated by their own professional groups. <strong>Law</strong>yers are<br />

accountable to their provincial law societies; underwriters, financial analysts, and<br />

retail investment advisors to the Investment Dealers Association of Canada (IDA);<br />

auditors are accountable to provincial institutes of chartered accountants; and credit<br />

rating agencies are accountable to the International Organization of Securities<br />

Commission.<br />

a. Provincial <strong>Law</strong> Societies<br />

In Ontario, lawyers are regulated by the <strong>Law</strong> Society of Upper Canada. The<br />

Society's Rules of Professional Conduct Rule 2.02(5) holds that lawyers cannot<br />

knowingly assist in or encourage any dishonesty or crime, or tell their client how to<br />

violate the law and avoid punishment. 1 2 The comments to this rule indicate that a<br />

lawyer has an obligation to investigate any suspicions both prior to and during a<br />

retainer.' 13 Other provinces have similar rules, although Ontario is the only province<br />

to require "up the ladder" reporting; that is, lawyers must inform representatives of<br />

the organization up through the board of directors if it is known that the client is, has<br />

previously, or will engage in dishonest, fraudulent, or illegal conduct."' In Ontario,<br />

lawyers must also withdraw from acting in the matter should corrective action not be<br />

taken."'<br />

Even with this obligation for lawyers, every province recognizes the<br />

confidential nature of the solicitor-client relationship. Ontario Rules of Professional<br />

Conduct Rule 2.03 governs confidentiality." 6 Generally confidentiality is protected<br />

across the board, meaning there is little room for whistleblowing. Rule 2.03(2) and<br />

(3) outline the areas of justified disclosure in Ontario. The commentary confirms<br />

that when a lawyer becomes aware that a client that may commit a fraudulent,<br />

criminal, dishonest, or illegal act, he or she is prevented from passing any<br />

confidential information to the correct authorities, though he or she must follow the<br />

procedures outlined above in Rule 2.02." 7 The confidential information provisions in<br />

all other provinces except Alberta and Saskatchewan also prevent lawyers from<br />

whistleblowing on corporate wrongdoing." ' As whistleblowing is not often an option<br />

for lawyers, most jurisdictions either allow or oblige lawyers to withdraw from a case<br />

where the client persists in instructing the lawyer to breach ethics. For corporate<br />

counsel, withdrawal means refusing to implement the client's instructions in that<br />

matter, while continuing to advise the corporation or government in other respectsincluding,<br />

in certain cases, resigning." 9<br />

112. LAW SOCIETY OF UPPER CANADA, RULES OF PROF'L CONDUCT R. 2.02(5) cmt. (2005), R.<br />

2.02(5.1), R. 2.02(5.2) cmt. (2004).<br />

113. Id. R. 2.02(5) cmt.<br />

114. Id. R. 2.02(5.1).<br />

115. Id., R. 2.02(5.1), R. 2.02(5.2), and R. 2.02(5.2) cmt. (2004).<br />

116. Id. R. 2.03.<br />

117. Id. R. 2.02.<br />

118. LAW SOCIETY OF ALBERTA, CODE OF PROF'L CONDUCT HANDBOOK, ch. 5.<br />

119. LAW SOCIETY OF ALBERTA. CODE OF PROF'L CONDUCT, ch. 12, R. 4 cmt. 4 (2006).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 457 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

If a lawyer does not fulfill his or her gatekeeper function, he or she could be<br />

disbarred, reprimanded, suspended, or face other conditions on practicing. Some<br />

law societies can issue any order they deem appropriate for breaches of professional<br />

conduct, which opens up the possibility for fines and/or payments to third parties. 1 20<br />

Fines are rarely imposed as penalties,' 2 ' and the author has found no evidence of<br />

payments to third parties being ordered. Some provinces do not give law societies<br />

the ability to impose sanctions beyond disbarment, reprimand, suspensions, or<br />

conditions. 1 22<br />

b. Investment Dealers Association of Canada<br />

Underwriters, financial analysts, and retail investment advisors all fall under the<br />

scope of the Investment Dealers Association of Canada (IDA). The IDA's mission<br />

is to protect investors and enhance the efficiency and competitiveness of Canadian<br />

capital markets.' 23 The IDA enforces rules and regulations regarding the sales,<br />

business, and financial practices of its Member firms and its Approved Persons,<br />

investigates complaints, and disciplines Members and Approved Persons.<br />

One IDA By-<strong>Law</strong>, No. 29, deals with ethics and business conduct, charging its<br />

members to "observe high standards of ethics" and to "not engage in any business<br />

124<br />

conduct or practice which is unbecoming or detrimental to the public interest.'<br />

Policy No. 5 provides an elaboration on the By-<strong>Law</strong>, and provides in section 4.1 that<br />

its members have a duty to deal fairly and "act fairly, honestly and in good faith"; 12 1<br />

section 4.2 provides that the public interest is held in high regard; 26 and section 4.5<br />

states that members shall ensure that their trading does not contravene any criminal<br />

and regulatory laws. 27 Most importantly, with regard to withholding support and<br />

services from clients engaging in misconduct, if underwriters fail to act properly, they<br />

may be held liable under section 4.6 with regard to misrepresentation and false<br />

remarks. The sanctions if the standard of business conduct falls below the standard<br />

set by the policy and by-laws are contained in section 5 of IDA Policy No. 5,<br />

including fines of up to $1 million per offence or (in the case of a Member) triple the<br />

amount of the benefit from the breach, reprimands, suspension or termination of<br />

approval, or expulsion. 2 1<br />

120. See e.g. <strong>Law</strong> Society Act, R.S.O., ch. L 8, § 35 (1990); Legal Profession Act, S.S., ch. L 10.1. §<br />

55(2) (1990-91); Legal Profession Act, C.C.S.M. ch. L 107, § 72(1) (2002); Legal Profession Act, S.N.S., ch.<br />

28, § 45(4) (2004); <strong>Law</strong> Society Act, 1999, S.N.L., ch. L 9.1, § 48(3) (1999); and <strong>Law</strong> Society Act, S.N.B., ch.<br />

89. § 51(1) (1995).<br />

121. GAVIN MCKENZIE, LAWYERS AND ETHICS: PROFESSIONAL RESPONSIBILITY AND DISCIPLINE<br />

(Thompson Canada 1993).<br />

122. See, e.g., Legal Profession Act, R.S.A., c. L-8. § 72 (2000). Some jurisdictions allow fines, but give<br />

the society no residual discretion. British Columbia allows fines up to a maximum of $20,000: Legal<br />

Professions Act, S.B.C., ch. 8, § 38 (1990). Prince Edward Island allows fines up to a maximum of $10,000:<br />

Legal Profession Act, R.S.P.E.I., ch. L 6.1, § 38(1) (1988). Quebec allows a maximum fine of $6000:<br />

Professional Code, R.S.Q. c. C-26, § 156.<br />

123. IDA, About the IDA: Roles and Responsibilities, http://www.ida.ca/About/Roles-en.asp.<br />

124. IDA By-<strong>Law</strong> No. 29, Business Conduct at 29.1.<br />

125. IDA Policy No. 5, Code of Conduct for IDA Member Firms Trading in Domestic Debt Markets,<br />

§ 4.1.<br />

126. Id. at § 4.2.<br />

127. Id. at § 4.5.<br />

128. Id. at §5.3.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 458 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

Retail investment advisors are generally employed by investment firms which,<br />

like underwriters, are regulated by the IDA and must adhere to its by-laws, rules,<br />

and regulations. In addition, investment advisors themselves must personally<br />

register as a Registered Representative (RR) or Investment Representative (IR). 20<br />

An RR has full authority to deal with the public and can advise on trades. 3 An IR<br />

cannot advise on trades although he or she can take unsolicited client orders. 3 ' For<br />

both types of registration an individual must successfully complete the Canadian<br />

Securities Course, the Conduct and Practices Handbook Exam, and a training<br />

program offered by his or her firm. For IRs, the length of the training course is 30<br />

days, and for RRs, the length of the training course is 90 days. After registration, six<br />

months of extra internal supervision is required. RRs must then go on to complete<br />

an additional course (the Professional Financial Planning Course or Investment<br />

Management Techniques Course) within 30 months of registration. Along with the<br />

registration, the IDA imposes an obligation on RRs to take "reasonable precautions<br />

to ensure that any transaction in which he or she<br />

32<br />

is involved is transacted to the<br />

benefit of and best interests of his or her client.'<br />

The IDA regulates investment firms that employ financial analysts, and IDA<br />

members have a supervisory responsibility over their employees. 33 While they are<br />

subject to the same rules as other firm employees, financial analysts are not required<br />

to be registered. However, senior analysts are usually officers and/or directors of<br />

Member firms, and therefore subject to additional liability. The IDA provisions that<br />

govern objectivity and accuracy do not specifically relate to analysts, but rules like<br />

2(b), which ensures a level of objectivity and accuracy of information, can be<br />

applied. 34 There is also an explicit duty for analysts to prevent any potential<br />

conflicts of interests in rule 11, and rule 17 obliges them to uphold the Chartered<br />

Financial Analyst (CFA) Institute's Code of Ethics and Standards of Professional<br />

Conduct.' 35 Breach of IDA Rules will lead to investigation for all gatekeepers<br />

subject to them, and if the investigation leads to a need for further action, a<br />

disciplinary hearing will be held. The IDA can impose penalties on both registered<br />

employees and Member firms, including: a reprimand, fines, suspension,<br />

prohibitions, termination, and expulsion of membership.' 36<br />

Even without the IDA obligation, many financial analysts are subject to the<br />

Code of Ethics and Standards of Professional Conduct. 37 The CFA does not cover<br />

all securities analysts, since membership in the organization is not a requirement<br />

according to provincial securities legislation. However, those that are must adhere<br />

129. Investment Dealers Association of Canada, IDA Bulletin # 2663, Policy No. 6 - Part III the<br />

Continuing Education Program and Parameters and Guidelines for the Securities Industry Continuing<br />

Education Program (November 1999), http://www.ida.ca/Files/BulletinsNotices/Bulletins/B2663-en.pdf.<br />

130. Id.<br />

131. Id.<br />

132. Investment Dealers Association of Canada, IDA Bulletin # 3332, Discipline Penalties Imposed on<br />

Alan Bruce Alexander Thomson - Violations of By-law 29.1 (Sept. 2004),<br />

http://www.ida.ca/Files/BulletinsNotices/Bulletins/B3332-en.pdf.<br />

133. Securities Industry Committee, supra note 40, at 37.<br />

134. IDA Policy No. 11, Research Restrictions and Disclosure Requirements, R. 2(b).<br />

135. Id. R. 11 and R. 17.<br />

136. IDA, Enforcement: Disciplinary Actions (Jan. 2005),<br />

http://www.ida.ca/Enforcement/FactsAndStats/DisciplinaryActions-en.asp.<br />

137. CFA Institute, Code of Ethics and Standards of Professional Conduct (2005).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 459 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

to the Code of Ethics, which obliges its members to act with integrity and in an<br />

ethical manner. 38 The Standards of Professional Conduct sets out a guideline that<br />

,'members and Candidates must not knowingly make any misrepresentations relating<br />

to investment analysis, recommendations, actions, or other professional activities.,1 39<br />

The guideline on misconduct states that "members and Candidates must not engage<br />

in any professional misconduct involving dishonesty, fraud, or deceit or commit any<br />

act that reflects adversely on their professional reputation, integrity, or<br />

competence. '40 Violation of the Code results in loss of membership, but as it is not a<br />

requirement for industry participation, this sanction has limited force.<br />

c. Provincial Institutes of Chartered Accountants<br />

The Provincial Institutes of Chartered Accountants Rules of Professional<br />

Conduct (Rules) forms the professional obligations of CAs that perform audits.''<br />

With the exception of the Quebec Code of Ethics, the Rules are substantively<br />

equivalent across all provinces. 142 Most importantly, Rule 213 of the Rules of<br />

Professional Conduct, explicitly states "a member, student or firm shall not<br />

knowingly associate with any unlawful activity."' 43 As such, upon detection of client<br />

misconduct, an auditor may be explicitly obligated to withhold support and services.<br />

However, often client misconduct falls into a grey area, and may not be<br />

considered outright unlawful. As such, other rules which pertain to the auditor's<br />

liability as gatekeeper include the following: Rule 201.1 provides, "a member,<br />

student or firm shall act at all times in a manner which will maintain the good<br />

reputation of the profession and its ability to serve the public interest"; Rule 202<br />

provides, "a member, student or firm shall perform professional services with<br />

integrity and due care"; and Rule 205 provides, "a member, student, or firm shall not<br />

sign or make false or misleading documents and oral representations."'" In<br />

particular Rule 204.1, which pertains to maintaining independence in any accounting<br />

engagement, provides that any member of a firm who participates in an engagement<br />

shall be and remain free of any influence impairing the professional judgment or<br />

objectivity of the member, or which a reasonable observer thinks might impair the<br />

member.' 45 Rule 206 deals with professional standards, and carries an ethical<br />

138. Id.<br />

139. Id. R. I(c).<br />

140. Id. R. I(d).<br />

141. Institute of Chartered Accountants of Ontario, Rules of Professional Conduct; Institute of<br />

Chartered Accountants of British Columbia, Rules of Professional Conduct; Institute of Chartered<br />

Accountants of Alberta, Rules of Professional Conduct; Institute of Chartered Accountants of Manitoba,<br />

Rules of Professional Conduct; New Brunswick Institute of Chartered Accountants, Rules of Professional<br />

Conduct; Institute of Chartered Accountants of Newfoundland, Rules of Professional Conduct; Institute of<br />

Chartered Accountants of Nova Scotia, Rules of Professional Conduct; Institute of Chartered Accountants<br />

of Prince Edward Island, Rules of Professional Conduct; Ordre des comptables agrd6s du Quebec, Code of<br />

Ethics of Chartered Accountants; Institute of Chartered Accountants of Saskatchewan, Rules of<br />

Professional Conduct; Institute of Chartered Accountants of Northwest Territories, Rules of Professional<br />

Conduct.<br />

142. Id.<br />

143. Id.<br />

144. Id.; see also Qu6bec, id. R. 5, 23, and 34.<br />

145. Id.; see also Quebec, id., R. 36.4.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 460 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

standard of conduct not found in provincial securities legislation or the corporate<br />

statutes. 146<br />

The Professional Conduct Committee investigates all written complaints<br />

received about Institute members, students, and firms for violations of the Institute's<br />

rules of professional conduct, regulations, or bylaws. When the Professional<br />

Conduct Committee lays a charge or charges of professional misconduct against a<br />

member, student or firm, a formal hearing is held in front of the Institute's<br />

disciplinary committee; if a finding of guilt is made, the disciplinary committee has<br />

the power to order that the member, student or firm be: reprimanded; fined; charged<br />

the costs of the investigation and hearing; suspended from the Institute; struck off<br />

the register of students; or expelled from membership in the Institute.' The CGA<br />

and the CMA regulatory bodies also have their own sets of rules of professional<br />

conduct that are similar to the Rules outlined above. A detailed examination of<br />

these rules is not necessary as the Canadian Public Accountability Board and<br />

accompanying legislation in most instances require members to follow the Rules.<br />

Auditors are also regulated under the Canadian Public Accounting Board<br />

(CPAB). 4 National Instrument 52-108 requires auditors of reporting issuers to be<br />

members in good standing with the CPAB, a new independent public oversight<br />

system that includes regular and rigorous inspections of auditors of Canada's public<br />

companies. 149 Section 300 of the CPAB Rules sets out the professional standards<br />

that audit firms must adhere to, which generally echoes the ethical standards<br />

imposed by the professional regulatory bodies that have jurisdiction over them. 50 If<br />

a violation occurs, sanctions are prescribed on the audit firm under CPAB Rules<br />

section 601 including: additional professional education for some or all of the<br />

designated professionals of a participating audit firm; the design, adoption or<br />

implementation of policies by a participating audit firm to ensure its compliance with<br />

the CPAB Rules; and appointment of an independent monitor, subject to the<br />

approval of the Board, to observe and report to the Board on a participating audit<br />

firm's compliance with the CPAB Rules. '<br />

d. International Organization of Securities Commission<br />

Unlike CPAB and other regulatory bodies, the International Organization of<br />

Securities Commission's (IOSCO) Code of Conduct Fundamentals (IOSCO Code)' 52<br />

does not act as a code of conduct to which CRAs are expected to adhere. Instead it<br />

contains a set of provisions that the IOSCO expects all CRAs will incorporate and<br />

give full effect to in their codes of conduct. The IOSCO Code addresses issues<br />

including how CRAs should avoid or mitigate potential conflicts of interest, improve<br />

146. Id.; see also Qudbec, id. R. 19.<br />

147. See generally Institute of Chartered Accountants, supra note 141 and accompanying text.<br />

148. National Instrument 52-108 Auditor Oversight, 27 O.S.C.B. 874 (2004)<br />

149. 27 OSCB 3227 (2004). For greater detail see P. Puri and A. Pritchard, The Regulation of Public<br />

Auditing in Canada and the United <strong>State</strong>s: Self-Regulation or Government Regulation (Fraser Institute<br />

2006).<br />

150. CPAB Rules, § 303(a) and (b).<br />

151. Id.§ 601.<br />

152. International Organization of Securities Commissions, Code of Conduct Fundamentals (Dec.<br />

2004) [hereinafter IOSCO Code]..<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 461 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

the transparency of the ratings process, and protect their integrity and independence<br />

while dealing fairly with issuers, investors, and other market participants.'" The<br />

liabilities of CRAs for failing to withhold their support and services upon detection<br />

of misconduct are primarily implicit. Rule 1.6 of the IOSCO Code deals with the<br />

quality of the rating process, and states that "the CRA and its analysts should take<br />

steps to avoid issuing any credit analyses or reports that contain misrepresentations<br />

or are otherwise misleading as to the general creditworthiness of an issuer or<br />

obligation."' 54 While the IOSCO Code provides indications on how CRAs should<br />

conduct their business, it should be noted that currently there is no mandatory<br />

disclosure of CRAs' codes of conduct under any provincial securities legislation, and<br />

no explicit sanctions for non-compliance.<br />

D. Criminal and Quasi-Criminal Liability<br />

The potential for criminal and quasi-criminal liability can be demonstrated<br />

through an examination of provisions that can apply to many gatekeepers. For<br />

example, under provincial securities law, anyone who authorizes, permits, or<br />

acquiesces in a contravention of the provincial securities acts may be liable for a fine<br />

of not more than $5 million and/or imprisonment for a period of up to five years less<br />

one day in Ontario, British Columbia, and Alberta.1 5 The penalties vary by<br />

province, but the underlying behaviour triggering the offence is the same. Also, it is<br />

important to note that this behaviour is only quasi-criminal, since the legislation is<br />

provincial, thus the mens rea requirement for this offence is one of strict liability.' 5 6<br />

Only a due diligence defence will be afforded a director who has authorized,<br />

permitted, or acquiesced to the company's violation of securities law.<br />

There is also federal legislation with quasi-criminal effects. Under the CBCA<br />

and parallel provincial corporate law statutes, § 250(1) states:<br />

a person who makes or assists in making a report, return, notice, or other<br />

document required by this Act or the regulations to be sent to ...any<br />

person that<br />

(a) contains an untrue statement of a material fact, or<br />

(b) omits to state a material fact required therein or necessary to make a<br />

statement contained therein not misleading in the light of the<br />

circumstances in which it was made...<br />

153. International Organization of Securities Commissions, Press Release, Task Force of Securities<br />

Regulators from Major Markets Agrees on Code of Conduct Fundamentals for Credit Rating Agencies<br />

(December 2004).<br />

154. IOSCO Code, supra note 152, r.1.6.<br />

155. OSA, supra note 59, § 122(3); ASA, supra note 59, § 194(3); BCSC, supra note 59, § 155(3). In<br />

Ontario, for example, § 122 of the OSA makes it an offence to make a materially misleading or untrue<br />

statement or material omission in any document required to be filed or furnished under Ontario securities<br />

legislation.<br />

156. R. v. City of Sault Ste. Marie, 2 S.C.R. 1299 (1978) (Can.).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 462 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

is guilty of an offence and liable on summary conviction to a fine not<br />

exceeding $5000 or to imprisonment for a term not exceeding six months<br />

or to both.'"<br />

In addition, if the corporation itself does any of the above, any director or officer of<br />

the corporation who knowingly authorized, permitted or acquiesced in the<br />

commission of the offence is a party to and guilty of the offence and is liable on<br />

summary conviction to the same penalties as listed above. 5 A due diligence defence<br />

is provided under the corporate statutes such that no person is guilty of a quasicriminal<br />

offence "if the person did not know, and in the exercise of reasonable<br />

diligence could not have known, of the untrue statement or omission. ' 5 0 1<br />

Along with quasi-criminal liability, directors can be held criminally liable<br />

through various sections of the Criminal Code of Canada (CC), including section<br />

400, under which it is an offence to make, circulate, or publish a prospectus that is<br />

known to be false in a material particular<br />

with intent<br />

(a) to induce persons to become shareholders or partners in a company,<br />

(b) to deceive or defraud the members, shareholders or creditors ... of a<br />

company, or<br />

(c)<br />

to induce any person to<br />

(i)<br />

entrust or advance anything to a company, or<br />

(ii) enter into any security for the benefit of a company .... '60<br />

Other applicable sections include section 382, which creates an indictable offence<br />

liable to imprisonment for a term not exceeding 10 years for entering transactions<br />

that create false or misleading appearances of market activity or a misleading<br />

appearance as to the market price of a security, 16" ' and 380(2) which extends the<br />

prohibition against fraud to any deceit, falsehood or fraudulent practice that affects<br />

the public market price of stocks or shares and creates an indictable offence liable to<br />

157. CBCA, supra note 41, § 250; ABCA, supra note 41, § 251; SBCA, supra note 35, § 300; NBBCA,<br />

supra note 41, § 175; NFCA, supra note 4135, s.§ 504; YBCA, supra note 41, at § 251; NWTBCA, supra<br />

note 41, § 252. See also OBCA, supra note 41, § 256 (liability in Ontario is $2,000 or imprisonment for 1<br />

year, or $25,000 for a corporate body); BCBCA, supra note 41, §§ 427-428 (liability in B.C. is $10,000 for an<br />

individual, or $25,000 if not an individual). Note that Companies Act, R.S.Q. c. C-38, §§ 108 and 201,<br />

creates liability for untrue entries in the corporate books $100 per entry and liability for damages and<br />

Companies Act, R.S.P.E.I., c. C-14, § 54 (1988) creates liability for damages stemming from<br />

misrepresentations in the corporate books. There does not appear to be quasi-criminal liability under the<br />

NSCA, supra note 42.<br />

158. NSCA, supra note 42.<br />

159. Id.<br />

160. Criminal Code, R.S.C., ch. C-46, § 400 (1985).<br />

161. Id. § 382<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 463 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

imprisonment for a term not exceeding 14 years.' 62 Even when the directors are not<br />

the party for actually committing the offence, they may also be liable for aiding and<br />

abetting, 163 as exemplified in the case of R. v. Fell. 64<br />

Section 380.1 was introduced in March 2004, establishing four aggravating<br />

circumstances that a court can consider when imposing a sentence for market fraud<br />

offences. 65 A court can impose tougher penalties if:<br />

(a) the value of the fraud committed exceeded one million dollars;<br />

(b) the offence adversely affected, or had the potential to adversely affect, the<br />

stability of the Canadian economy or financial system or any financial<br />

market in Canada or investor confidence in such a financial market;<br />

(c) the offence involved a large number of victims; and<br />

(d) in committing the offence, the offender took advantage the high regard in<br />

which the offender was held in the community. '6 4<br />

These provisions apply equally to other corporate gatekeepers, including<br />

lawyers. <strong>Law</strong>yers face quasi-criminal liability through the Ontario Provincial<br />

Offences Act under sections 77 and 78, which make a lawyer party to an offence<br />

under provincial securities or corporate legislation if he or she did or omitted to do<br />

anything to aid or abet a client in committing an offence, or if he or she counseled<br />

another person to commit an offence.' 67 Some other provinces have similar<br />

legislation.<br />

There are a number of examples where lawyers have become liable for a<br />

criminal action under the CC through their actions on behalf of a corporation, which<br />

may be characterized as a failure in performing their gatekeeping function. In one<br />

example, R. v. Sahaidak, a lawyer was held criminally liable for a fraudulent stock<br />

scheme, despite being neither the "creator" nor the "driving force" behind the<br />

scheme. 6 However, the judge noted that "there are offences... that need lawyers<br />

in order to be committed" and found the lawyer to have been "an active participant<br />

in each of the frauds and an important participant."' 69 In another example, R. v.<br />

Shead, a lawyer was held liable for several counts of fraud for making negligent<br />

disclosures to investors.' 0 This case suggests a requirement of subjective knowledge<br />

of the facts to draw a legal conclusion of fraud (i.e., objectively dishonest conduct<br />

and deprivation caused by the dishonest act) and an action to aid in the commission<br />

of the crime, which is a high mens rea threshold to be met. A lawyer is generally<br />

unable to control a corporate client from engaging in the dishonest act unless the<br />

dishonest act is reliant upon an action by the lawyer. Thus, in general, the<br />

withholding of consent should be sufficient to prevent a fraudulent act; intentionally<br />

aiding a client when there is knowledge of a criminal action will constitute aiding and<br />

abetting under the CC.<br />

162. Id. § 380(2).<br />

163. Id. § 21(1).<br />

164. 34 O.R. (2d) 665 (C.A. 1981).<br />

165. Criminal Code, supra note 160, § 380.1.<br />

166. Id.<br />

167. Provincial Offences Act, R.S.O., ch. P-33 (1990).<br />

168. R. v. Sahaidak, No. 2792, 10 W.C.B. (2d) 245 (Ont. H.C. Jan. 20, 1990), available at 1990 W.C.B.J.<br />

LEXIS 8591, 11.<br />

169. Id.<br />

170. R. v. Shead, [1996] 114 Man. R.2d 42 (Can.).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 464 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

All categories of corporate gatekeepers can be exposed to criminal liability<br />

under the CC, depending on the degree of misconduct. Auditors, credit rating<br />

agencies, financial analysts, and retail investment advisors are all also liable to quasicriminal<br />

charges under securities and corporate legislation. Underwriters and<br />

CRAs, through the adoption of Bill C-45, can be held liable as an "organization,<br />

which includes a law firm, based on criminal activity of senior officers of the<br />

organization. 7 '<br />

IV.<br />

LOCATING THE CANADIAN SYSTEM IN AN INTERNATIONAL<br />

CONTEXT<br />

A. Directors<br />

In the United <strong>State</strong>s, the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 (Sarbanes-Oxley)<br />

imposes increased responsibilities on directors, without direct legal penalties for<br />

directors who breach those responsibilities. 2 In the United Kingdom, there have<br />

been recent amendments to company law which have relaxed the provisions<br />

protecting directors and other company officers from liability.' 73 Amongst these<br />

changes is the introduction of director liability to third parties, under sections 19 and<br />

20 of the Companies (Audit, Investigations and Community Enterprise) Act 2004<br />

(C(AICE)). 7 ' The current Canadian gatekeeper liability regime for directors is in<br />

line with the U.S. model, but has not gone the U.K. route of attaching additional<br />

liability to the additional responsibilities now placed upon directors, and particularly<br />

independent directors, as gatekeepers.<br />

The academic literature suggests that the exact nature of the gatekeeping role<br />

that directors should play remains unclear. For example, James Kirkbride and Steve<br />

Letza suggest that non-executive directors might serve as internal monitors of CEO<br />

behaviour because they have access to privileged information about firm operations,<br />

which is inaccessible to public enforcement officials. 7 ' However, they outline some<br />

of the problems associated with imposing gatekeeper liability, including the cost<br />

element; if gatekeepers cannot shift their liability risks, they will charge higher<br />

premiums.' 76 This suggests that imposing increased liability on directors as<br />

gatekeepers does not necessarily contribute to a more effective gatekeeper liability<br />

regime.<br />

Indeed, public opinion does not support an increase in sources of director<br />

liability."' Instead, increasing transparency and disclosure about directors' salaries<br />

171. For a more detailed discussion see Darcy L. MacPherson, Extending Corporate Criminal<br />

Liability?: Some Thoughts on Bill C-45, 30 MAN. L.J. 253 (2004).<br />

172. Public Company Accounting Reform and Investor Protection Act (Sarbanes-Oxley) 18 U.S.C. §<br />

7261 (2002) [hereinafter Sarbanes-Oxley].<br />

173. See Companies (Audit, Investigations, and Community Enterprise) Act, 2004, ch. 27, § 19-20<br />

(U.K), available at http://www.opsi.gov.uk/acts/acts2004/ukpga-20040027-en.pdf [hereinafter C(AICE)].<br />

174. Id.<br />

175. See James Kirkbride & Steve Letza, Can the Non-Executive Director Be an Effective Gatekeeper?<br />

The Possible Development of a Legal Framework of Accountability, 13 CORP. GOv. 542, 544 (2005).<br />

176. Id.<br />

177. The Ditchley Foundation Conference, Confidence, Control and Compensation: Questions for<br />

the Modern Corporation (Sept. 5-7, 2003), at http://www.ditchley.co.uk/page/175/modern-corporation.htm.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 465 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

may help allay general concerns. The sharp rise in directors' salaries relative to the<br />

salaries of the average employee was cited as a major problem by many Ditchley<br />

Foundation conference participants, including business people, regulators, and<br />

politicians.' Further demonstrating the problem with directors' salaries, the<br />

Ontario Teachers' Pension Plan released a report in June of 2006 showing little<br />

correlation between CEO pay and total stock return.' 79 To combat the public<br />

perception problems with directors' compensation, the Canadian Coalition for Good<br />

Governance has suggested transparency guidelines and assists in their<br />

implementation.'9<br />

Additionally, the recent introduction of the secondary market civil liability<br />

scheme in Ontario presents an opportunity to evaluate the impact of increased<br />

gatekeeper liability for directors and at the same time examine the judiciary's role in<br />

applying such a regime. Further amendments are not recommended until this<br />

experience has been fully evaluated in the Canadian context. Following an<br />

evaluation of the current regime, further consideration should be given to attaching<br />

increased liability to the added responsibilities placed on directors, and in particular,<br />

independent directors.<br />

B. <strong>Law</strong>yers<br />

In Canada, the United <strong>State</strong>s, and the United Kingdom, lawyers are regulated<br />

both by law societies and securities statutes. Under section 307 of Sarbanes-Oxley,<br />

the SEC has developed rules of professional conduct for lawyers, and those who<br />

violate the rules are subject to all remedies and sanctions available to the SEC for<br />

the violation of federal securities laws. 8 ' <strong>Law</strong>yers are also regulated by their state<br />

bar association, many of which have adopted the American Bar Association's Model<br />

Rules of Professional Conduct (Model Rules), though it is up to each state bar<br />

association to develop its own rules and standards. In the U.K., the <strong>Law</strong> Society sets<br />

out The Guide to the Professional Conduct of Solicitors.' <strong>Law</strong>yers in the U.K. are<br />

also regulated under the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 (FSMA 2000). 8 1<br />

Unlike the U.S. model and more akin to the U.K. model, the Canadian model<br />

for gatekeeper liability for lawyers clearly assigns the key regulatory function to the<br />

provincial law societies. The benefit of this model is that the problem of conflicting<br />

standards that exists in the U.S. between the Rules of Professional Conduct, set by<br />

each state Bar Association and the SEC rules does not arise. It is also the case that<br />

the law societies are keenly aware of the competing tensions between lawyers'<br />

gatekeeping function and the confidentiality requirements that are required<br />

178. Id.<br />

179. See INSTITUTIONAL SHAREHOLDER SERVICES, SPOTLIGHT ON EXECUTIVE PAY AND BOARD<br />

ACCOUNTABILITY 38 (2006), http://www.issproxy.com/pdf/2006PostSeasonReportFINAL.pdf (last visited<br />

Apr. 16, 2007).<br />

180. See Good Governance Guidelines for Principled Executive Compensation, (Canadian Coalition<br />

for Good Governance, Working Paper, 2006), http://www.ccgg.ca/guidelines/executive-compensation/<br />

(follow "Guidelines for Principled Executive Compensation" hyperlink) (last visited Apr. 16, 2007).<br />

181. Sarbanes-Oxley, 18 U.S.C. § 307 (2005).<br />

182. See generally THE GUIDE TO THE PROFESSIONAL CONDUCT OF SOLICITORS, (Nicola Taylor ed.,<br />

8th ed. 1999).<br />

183. See generally Financial Services and Markets Act 2000, c.8 (U.K.), available at<br />

http://www.opsi.gov.uk/acts/acts2000/20000008.htm.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 466 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

generally of all lawyers. However, there is variation among the law societies to the<br />

extent they have created specific rules to address lawyers' gatekeeping function.<br />

Ontario appears to have created the model most similar to the U.S. model, striking a<br />

balance between lawyers' roles as gatekeepers and advocates.<br />

To improve the competitiveness of Canadian capital markets, it is<br />

recommended that each law society give consideration to adopting a similar set of<br />

rules-with the input of each provincial securities commission. A more uniform and<br />

comprehensive set of rules of professional conduct will simplify the existing system<br />

and at the same time ease investors' concerns about the role that lawyers are playing<br />

in Canadian capital markets. Following a provincial consultation process, it may be<br />

helpful to form a national working group to develop a uniform set of rules of<br />

professional conduct.<br />

C. Auditors<br />

After the financial collapse of Enron, there was very little public confidence in<br />

auditors and accountants. While it was an American corporation, seventy-three<br />

percent of Canadians doubted their public protections, and believed an Enron-like<br />

scandal would take place there as well.' 8 Further, inconsistencies between the<br />

Canadian and American systems have since been highlighted by Al Rosen, founder<br />

of the forensic accounting firm Rosen & Associates Ltd.' 85 He contends that in 2003,<br />

two-thirds of Canadian companies would have lower reported profits if American<br />

accounting rules were used in place of their Canadian counterparts. 186 Recent<br />

Canadian reforms, detailed below, have helped to address these concerns, and this<br />

article offers additional suggestions to increase public confidence in auditors further.<br />

In the U.S., Sarbanes-Oxley imposed extensive federal regulation on the<br />

accounting profession.' 87 The act created the Public Company Accounting Oversight<br />

Board (PCAOB) to oversee the audit of public companies. 18 ' Accounting firms must<br />

register with the PCAOB which has broad powers to promulgate binding rules and<br />

standards, conduct investigations, and impose discipline; by shifting control of the<br />

accounting profession to a new body, the PCAOB aims to address the problem of<br />

accounting irregularities by establishing auditing standards and imposing<br />

professional discipline.' 89<br />

The U.K.'s counterpart to the PCOAB is the Financial Reporting Council<br />

(FRC), an independent regulator for corporate reporting and governance, created in<br />

April 2004 under the authority of the C(AICE) Act.' 9 The functions of the FRC<br />

include: establishing, monitoring, and enforcing accounting and auditing standards;<br />

184. Pollara, Canadians Expect Enron-Like Scandal Here, (May 2002), available at<br />

http://www.pollara.ca/LibraryNews/enron.html.<br />

185. Elizabeth Raymer, Accountants, Auditors Adopt New Rules, GLOBE AND MAIL (Canada), April<br />

1. 2003, at E6, available at<br />

http://www.globeinvestor.com/servlet/ArticleNews/story/GAM/20030401/CGACCT.<br />

186. Id.<br />

187. Sarbanes-Oxley, 18 U.S.C. § 7261 (2005).<br />

188. Sarbanes-Oxley, 15 U.S.C. § 7211 (2005).<br />

189. See Coffee Gatekeeper Failure and Reform, supra note 12, at 50.<br />

190. See C(AICE) Act, 2004, c. 27, § 14 (U.K.).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 467 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

regulating auditors; operating an independent investigation and disciplinary scheme<br />

for public interest cases; overseeing the regulatory activities of professional<br />

accountancy bodies; and promoting high standards of corporate governance. '<br />

Drawing on the U.S. and the U.K. models, the author believes that<br />

consideration should be given to conferring SRO status on the Canadian CPAB,<br />

subject to oversight by each of the securities regulators; the development of the<br />

CPAB provides an opportunity to improve the current gatekeeper liability regime<br />

for auditors. The current model, in which the CPAB relies on the ethical standards<br />

imposed by the industry bodies that have jurisdiction over auditors is consistent with<br />

the current Canadian self-regulatory approach. However, the status of the CPAB,<br />

as a creature of contract, is distinct from other similar organizations, creating issues<br />

concerning legitimacy, fairness and effectiveness. Currently, three SROs are<br />

recognized by the OSC and most other provincial securities regulators. The SROs<br />

currently recognized by the OSC are the Investment Dealers Association of Canada<br />

(IDA), the Mutual Fund Dealers Association of Canada (MFDA), and Market<br />

Regulation Services Inc. (RS). An SRO is an entity that represents registrants and is<br />

organized for the purpose of regulating the operations, standards of practice, and<br />

business conduct of its members and their representatives, with a view toward<br />

promoting the protection of investors and the public interest. It is recommended<br />

that the CPAB be accorded SRO status. This will improve investor confidence in<br />

both the CPAB, as regulator, and auditors, as gatekeepers, because their chief<br />

regulator-the provincial securities commission-will be perceived to be more<br />

legitimate and fair. At the same time this change will bring the Canadian position<br />

more in line with the U.S. and U.K. positions. In its capacity as an SRO, the CPAB<br />

will be in a better position to work with the industry bodies that regulate the<br />

accounting profession, thereby ensuring that the ideal level and form of gatekeeper<br />

liability for auditors is in place.<br />

The recent reforms and the changes proposed still leave the "two master<br />

problem" unresolved: auditors are still asked to treat the public as master, but<br />

continue to be paid by the corporation. 9 While this is recognized as an issue for<br />

gatekeepers, there is insufficient evidence to suggest that the current Canadian<br />

system needs to be completely overhauled at this time. Much has happened in<br />

Canada, the U.S., and the U.K. in the context of oversight of auditors over the last<br />

five years, and at this point, it is justifiable to resist making further changes and to<br />

allow the current system to develop while continuing to monitor it. In particular, the<br />

recent expansion of the number of accountants who may perform public audits<br />

should be observed. 93 The role that increased competition may play will be a factor<br />

in future regulatory decisions.<br />

191. Financial Reporting Council, Regulatory Strategy 2 (2006), http://www.frc.org.uk/about (follow<br />

the "Regulatory Strategy (Version 2.1)" hyperlink) (last visited Jan. 19, 2007).<br />

192. See Amy Shapiro, Who Pays the Auditor Calls the Tune?: Auditing Regulation and Clients'<br />

Incentives, 35 SETON HALL L. REV. 1029 (2005).<br />

193. Though most public accountants in Canada are certified accountants, as of 2005, certified general<br />

accountants were given the authority by provincial legislation to practise public accounting and auditing<br />

throughout Canada except Quebec. See Certified General Accountants Association of Canada, Public<br />

Accounting Rights for Certified General Accountants in Canada, May 2005, http://www.cga-<br />

online.org/servlet/portal/serve/library/news+and+media/_Product/carep_2005-<br />

05_pa-issue-brief?SESSION=najlvf7mjzYNnNo2ll38 (last visited Apr. 16, 2007).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 468 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

D. Credit Rating Agencies<br />

Commentators such as Frank Partnoy see CRAs as possessing little<br />

informational value.' 94 That is, while initial credit ratings provide guidance on<br />

purchases, it is unclear whether they provide any information beyond that already<br />

reflected in the "price talk" before a fixed instrument is issued. 9 Building on this<br />

critique, the best reforms should create incentives for CRAs to generate greater<br />

informational value while reducing the impact of ratings on markets. 96 In the<br />

current American context, Partnoy argues that CRAs are important not because<br />

they offer valuable information, but because they grant issuers "regulatory<br />

licenses"-that is, a good rating entitles the issuer to certain advantages related to<br />

regulation.97<br />

The effectiveness of CRA's gatekeeping role remains an open question.<br />

However, both the public perception and academic writing suggest that the existing<br />

liability regime does not instill confidence in capital markets and that there is room<br />

for modernizing Canadian securities legislation to improve the current situation.<br />

Accordingly, reforms to the current regime should focus on creating incentives for<br />

CRAs to generate informational value while reducing the market impact of ratings<br />

from a small group of CRAs.<br />

Given the uncertainty around CRAs' role and that there is no Canadian SRO<br />

or industry body charged with regulating CRAs, the securities commissions could<br />

play a critical role. Securities legislation should be amended to create a mandatory<br />

registration requirement for all CRAs and the provincial securities commissions<br />

should have the power to revoke or suspend registration of a wayward registrant.<br />

The disclosure obligations formulated by the IOSCO should be a condition to<br />

registration with the provincial securities commissions. The registration requirement<br />

would bring the treatment of CRAs more in line with the spirit of Canadian<br />

securities legislation as it relates to oversight of corporate gatekeepers. Registration<br />

would also create a threat of liability for rating malfeasance. Given concerns with<br />

imposing civil liability on CRAs, the ideal gatekeeper liability scheme should focus<br />

on administrative liability.' 9 The IOSCO Code, which CRAs have already generally<br />

adopted, presents a good model for imposing liability on CRAs.<br />

E. Financial Analysts<br />

Because of their unique intermediary role in capital markets, conflicts often<br />

arise between an analyst's duty to provide independent, objective advice to investor<br />

clients and pressures to support investment banking revenues.' 99 In the current<br />

194. Frank Partnoy, How and Why Credit-Rating Agencies Are Not Like Other Gatekeepers<br />

(unpublished manuscript, http://www.tcf.or.jp/data/20050928_FrankPartnoy.pdf).<br />

195. Id. n.13.<br />

196. Id.<br />

197. Id. at 28.<br />

198. See Stephane Rousseau, Enhancing the Accountability of Credit Rating Agencies: The Case for a<br />

Disclosure-Based Approach, CAPITAL MARKETS INsT. (Aug. 2005), available at<br />

http://www.rotman.utoronto.ca/cmi/papers/CRA-Study-Rousseau.pdf; see also Partnoy, supra note 196.<br />

199. SICAS Report, supra note 40, at 30.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 469 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

context, buy-side pressures on financial analysts are increasing in significance. For<br />

example, there is incentive for a mutual fund with large holdings in a stock to<br />

persuade an analyst not to put a "sell" recommendation on the stock that might<br />

contribute to a decline in its price. Following the SICAS Report, the IDA has taken<br />

significant measures to address the gatekeeping role played by analysts. However,<br />

given the recent reforms in the U.S. and the U.K. to bolster confidence in analysts<br />

function as gatekeepers, analysts should require more detailed disclosure by<br />

analysts, with accompanying liability for failure to disclose.<br />

U.S. reforms include SEC Regulation AC (Analyst Certification), 0 effective<br />

April 2003, which requires that when a broker, dealer, or covered person furnishes<br />

research prepared by a research analyst, the research must include a statement by<br />

the research analyst that the research truly reflects the analyst's opinion, and disclose<br />

whether or not an analyst received compensation in connection with his or her<br />

specific recommendations or views. ' Penalties under the Securities Act (or rules or<br />

regulations promulgated under the act, such as Regulation AC) may amount to fines<br />

of up to $10,000, or imprisonment of up to five years. 2<br />

The U.K.'s attempt to raise confidence in analysts' function is found in the<br />

Financial Services Authority's (FSA) Conduct of Business Sourcebook, section 7.17,<br />

which imposes "fair presentation" and disclosure requirements on analysts. 0 3 Since<br />

July 2004, firms that publish impartial research must have implemented a policy on<br />

identifying and managing conflicts to ensure analysts' impartiality. The FSA's rules<br />

set out minimum standards for conflict management processes and procedures. 2°'<br />

In Canada, IDA Policy No. 1125 should be amended to require: 1) a statement<br />

by the analyst that the research truly reflects the analyst's opinion; and 2) a<br />

prohibition on the investment banking department supervising or controlling<br />

analysts. Currently, Rule 2(b) requires that members disclose their system for<br />

ratings. More specific disclosure requirements, including identification of the analyst<br />

responsible for the production, dissemination of the research, and a statement by the<br />

analyst that the research truly reflects the analyst's opinion would bolster investors'<br />

confidence in the information that is provided. This reform will address both sellside<br />

and buy-side pressures facing financial analysts. In addition, members should<br />

not only set policies and procedures under IDA Rule 11 to avoid conflicts of interest,<br />

but also put in place controls and maintain records of supervision of analysts, and<br />

explicitly prohibit supervision and control of analysts by the investment banking<br />

200. 17 CFR § 242.100 (2005).<br />

201. See David J. Labhart, Securities Analysts: Why These Gatekeepers Have Abandoned Their Post,<br />

79 IND. L.J. 1037, 1054 (2004); see also Sec. and Exchange Commission, Regulation Analyst Certification<br />

(Apr. 2003), at http://www.sec.gov/rules/final/33-8193.htm.<br />

202. Securities Act, § 24, 15 U.S.C. § 77x.<br />

203. EMILIOs E. AVGOULEAS, MECHANICS AND REGULATION OF MARKET ABUSE: A LEGAL AND<br />

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS 366 (2005). Note that COB 7.17 was adopted in compliance with Article 6(5) of the<br />

MAD.<br />

204. FIN. SERVICES AUTHORITY, EX-POST ANALYSIS OF FSA's CONDUCT OF BUSINESS RULES ON<br />

CONFLICTS OF INTEREST IN INVESTMENT RESEARCH, (Sept. 2005), available at<br />

http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/other/post-analysis.pdf; see also CONFLICTS OF INTEREST IN INVESTMENT<br />

RESEARCH - FEEDBACK ON CP205 AND MADE HANDBOOK TEXT (March 2004), available at<br />

http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/policy/ps04_06.pdf.<br />

205. IDA Rule Book, Policy No. 11: Research Restrictions and Disclosure Requirements available at<br />

http://ida.knotia.ca/Knowledge/View/Documentcfn?Ktype=445&linkType=toc&dbID=200703341&toclD=<br />

796.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 470 2006-2007


2007<br />

CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA<br />

department. While such measures may appear to be outdated to the American<br />

reader given that similar measures were introduced in the U.S. in 2003 following<br />

Eliot Spitzer's investigation of conflicts of interest at Wall Street investment firms,<br />

they are not outdated in the Canadian context. 2 " These measures will bring the<br />

Canadian approach to gatekeeper liability for analysts more in line with the U.S. and<br />

the U.K. approaches, while maintaining the Canadian self-regulatory model.<br />

F<br />

Retail Investment Advisors<br />

Recent reform efforts regarding the liability of investment advisors in Canada<br />

have not focused on their role as corporate gatekeepers. Rather, the focus has been<br />

on establishing consumer protection mechanisms to address power imbalances in<br />

investment advisors' relationships with customers. The evidence suggests that<br />

consumer protection issues are the most pressing concern in the Canadian context.<br />

In certain instances, there is an overlap between liability introduced for more<br />

general consumer protection purposes and liability for failure to perform a corporate<br />

gatekeeping function. However, recent U.S. and U.K. reform efforts demonstrate<br />

that similar issues arise with respect to the role of analysts and investment advisors<br />

as corporate gatekeepers and accordingly, similar gatekeeper liability regimes<br />

(specific to the role of each gatekeeper) are justified and should be put into place. In<br />

the U.S., a full service investment advisor is obligated to recommend to a customer<br />

only those securities that match the customer's financial needs and goals (the<br />

"suitability obligation"), which is imposed on NASD members through Rules of Fair<br />

Practice (Conduct Rule 2310).207 Similar consumer protection issues arise in the<br />

American context, as breach of the suitability obligation has grown into the most<br />

commonly alleged basis of investor recovery against investment advisors. °0<br />

To a certain extent, the corporate gatekeeping role of investment advisors in<br />

Canada has been underestimated. The IDA, as a national SRO, is ideally suited to<br />

develop and implement a parallel policy to Policy No. 11, which is specific to the role<br />

of investment advisors. In particular, like Policy No. 11, the policy for investment<br />

advisors should build on the existing requirements in securities legislation for<br />

disclosure of possible conflicts resulting from the firm's relationships to issuers and<br />

clients. The new policy should respond to issues created by relationships in the firm,<br />

in the same way as Policy No. 11 seeks to respond to relationships between analysts<br />

and investment bankers.<br />

206. See generally Press Release, Eliot Spitzer, Office of New York <strong>State</strong> Attorney General, Conflict<br />

Probes Resolved at Citigroup and Morgan-Stanley (Apr. 28. 2003), available at<br />

http://www.oag.state.ny.us/press/2003/apr/apr28aO3.html.<br />

207. NASD Rules of Fair Practice: Conduct Rule 2310, at<br />

http://nasd.complinet.com/nasd/display/display.html?rbid= 189&element-id-Id= 9000500 (last visited Apr.<br />

17, 2007).<br />

208. Frederick Mark Gedicks, Suitability Claims and Purchases of Unrecommended Securities: An<br />

Agency Theory of Broker-Dealer Liability, 37 ARIZ. ST. L.J. 535, 543.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 471 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:441<br />

G. Underwriters<br />

Recent reforms in the U.S. have not focused on imposing or modifying the<br />

liability to which underwriters are subject as gatekeepers. For example, Choi writes<br />

that underwriters face strong incentives to act as certifiers; if they can provide<br />

credible assurances that an issuer's disclosures are truthful, investors will be willing<br />

to pay more for the issuer's securities. 2 ° The issuer will then pay more for the<br />

underwriter's certification service. There is less need for underwriter liability if they<br />

are incentivized to become more independent, and arguably better gatekeepers, by<br />

the market for independent certifiers. This argument applies to the Canadian<br />

context, suggesting that, like in the U.S., underwriters do not need to be subjected to<br />

additional liability.<br />

The reforms introduced by National Instrument 33-1052'<br />

help promote this<br />

model in Canada, and are consistent with the recent and proposed reforms in the<br />

U.S. and the U.K. to improve the effectiveness of underwriters' role as gatekeepers.<br />

The current regime does subject underwriters to civil, administrative and criminal<br />

liability for failure to perform their gatekeeping role. However, the focus is on<br />

disclosure of conflicts rather than on enlarging the instances and possibility for<br />

gatekeeper liability. In this way, the current regime is consistent with the model that<br />

Choi advocates. There is insufficient evidence to suggest that increasing or<br />

modifying the gatekeeper liability regime to which underwriters are currently subject<br />

will contribute to more competitive Canadian capital markets. At the same time,<br />

time constraint issues related to fast track offerings and the implications for the<br />

ability of underwriters to conduct adequate due diligence should continue to be<br />

monitored.<br />

V. CONCLUSION<br />

The analysis of the academic literature and the comparative context suggest<br />

that developing a streamlined approach to amending the gatekeeper liability scheme<br />

in Canada, which comes closer to the U.S. and the U.K. models, is not desirable.<br />

Overall, the polycentric legal environment for gatekeeper liability in Canada appears<br />

to be developing in a manner that gives gatekeepers guidelines on how to perform<br />

their functions, as well as adequate reason to do so. This can be demonstrated by<br />

indexes such as the Rotman School of Management's Board Shareholder<br />

Confidence Index, which found that governance scores, designed to reflect the<br />

degree to which elements of good governance are implemented by a company, have<br />

improved every year since 2003.21<br />

In examining the existing Canadian model where the boundaries between law<br />

and professional practice are somewhat blurred and subsystems of liability that apply<br />

to various gatekeepers differ both from gatekeeper to gatekeeper and also<br />

geographically, it became apparent that participants in the market and other<br />

209. Choi, supra note 9, at 962.<br />

210. BCSA, supra note 59, § 33-10.<br />

211. Michael Wilson, Corporate Governance Practices: Impact on Valuation, Canadian Coalition for<br />

Good Governance, in a speech given to the CFA Conference: Equity and Research Valuation Techniques<br />

(Dec. 2005),<br />

http:lwww.ccgg.calmedia/files/speeches/Speech%5Fto%5FCFA%5FDecember%5F1%5F2005.pdf, at 6.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 472 2006-2007


2007 CORPORATE GATEKEEPER LIABILITY IN CANADA 473<br />

members of the public may not be aware of the extent of the existing corporate<br />

gatekeeper liability regime in Canada. Awareness of the liability scheme plays a key<br />

role in developing confidence in Canadian capital markets. Accordingly, a final<br />

recommendation is made with regards to the widespread dissemination and<br />

availability of papers that seek to map out the existing gatekeeper liability regime in<br />

Canada and situate it in the context of recent academic literature and reforms in<br />

comparable jurisdictions.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 473 2006-2007


HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 474 2006-2007


Harmonization and Modernization in<br />

UNCITRAL's Legislative Guide on<br />

Insolvency <strong>Law</strong><br />

SUSAN BLOCK-LIEB* AND TERENCE HALLIDAY**<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. UNIFICATION, HARMONIZATION, AND MODERNIZATION ............................. 481<br />

A. The Shift Toward M odernization .............................................................. 488<br />

B. Redefining Harmonization to Meet the Challenges of Modernization .. 493<br />

II. UNCITRAL's LEGISLATIVE GUIDE ON INSOLVENCY LAW .......................... 498<br />

A. The Design of the Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> ........................ 498<br />

B . A rrays of R ule-Typ es .................................................................................. 502<br />

C. Rule- Types and Prospects for Consensual Decisionmaking ................... 506<br />

11. RULE-TYPES, MODERNIZATION AND HARMONIZATION ............................... 507<br />

A . M odernization ............................................................................................. 507<br />

B . H arm onization ............................................................................................ 509<br />

IV. MODERNIZATION AND GLOBAL LAW REFORM .............................................. 511<br />

Susan Block-Lieb, Professor of <strong>Law</strong>, Fordham University School of <strong>Law</strong>,<br />

sblocklieb@law.fordham.edu.<br />

Terence Halliday, Co-Director, Center on <strong>Law</strong> and Globalization, American Bar Foundation and<br />

University of Illinois College of <strong>Law</strong>; Senior Research Fellow, American Bar Foundation; Adjunct<br />

Professor of Sociology, Northwestern University, halliday@abfn.org. Professor Halliday's empirical<br />

research was funded through grants from the American Bar Foundation and National Science Foundation<br />

project SES-0214301.<br />

Both of us have been involved in UNCITRAL proceedings since 1999: Block-Lieb as a delegate<br />

from the American Bar Association and Halliday as a social scientific observer. Our findings are based on<br />

a combination of research methods, including participation in all formal Working Group and Commission<br />

sessions and informal expert meetings, statistical analysis of speech turns by all delegates, content analysis<br />

of all recommendations, and interviews of key delegates and UNCITRAL staffers during all phases of the<br />

proceedings.<br />

We thank Eric Bergsten, Ross Cranston, Bruce Carruthers, Whit Gray, Ted Janger, Ronald Mann,<br />

Junichi Matsushita, Christoph Paulus, John Pottow, Bob Rasmussen, Nick Segal, Joe Sweeney, Jay<br />

Westbrook, Jacob Ziegel, and others for comments and suggestions. An early version of this paper was<br />

presented at the bi-annual meeting of the International Academy of Commercial and Consumer <strong>Law</strong> at the<br />

University of Texas <strong>Law</strong> School; another version was presented at a conference we attended at Brooklyn<br />

<strong>Law</strong> School. We also greatly appreciate the research assistance provided by Jamie Hanlon (Fordham '08)<br />

and Jeanine Floyd (Fordham '08).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 475 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

If (international) commercial law is to keep pace with (international)<br />

commercial practices, then there has been much to do in the way of (international)<br />

law reform over the past forty years. During this period, commercial practices have<br />

changed substantially due to numerous factors: advances in telecommunications; the<br />

fall of the Soviet Union and attendant re-unification of Europe; systemic financial<br />

crises in South East Asia and South America; globalization; and developments,<br />

indeed, the revolution, in information and payment technology-the Internet and<br />

electronic funds transfers, to name just a few. To meet this challenge, UNCITRAL<br />

(the United Nations Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong>) has done more than<br />

simply reform trade law; it has also reconceived its very mission and the means by<br />

which it carried out its central purposes.<br />

Although the UN resolution creating UNCITRAL initially spoke in terms of<br />

the "progressive harmonization and unification" of the law of international trade, 1<br />

UNCITRAL now defines its mission as the "modernization and harmonization" of<br />

trade law. 2 Arguably, the task of modernizing the law of international trade was<br />

implicit in UNCITRAL's core mission. The resolution creating UNCITRAL<br />

referred to the "progressive" harmonization and unification of trade law, not simply<br />

its harmonization and unification.' This resolution emphasized that the progressive<br />

harmonization and unification of trade law followed from the United Nation's<br />

broader agenda of economic development and the promotion of friendly relations<br />

among nations<br />

Nonetheless, there may be an enormous difference between the task of<br />

harmonizing and unifying existing bodies of national law on the one hand, and the<br />

modernization of national laws on the other hand. Depending upon how one defines<br />

the task, 5 harmonization may present only minimal intrusions upon national<br />

1. G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), U.N. GAOR, 21st Sess., Supp. No. 16, U.N. Doc. A/6594 (Dec. 17, 1966),<br />

available at http://www.un.org/documents/ga/res/21/ares21.htm (follow "2205 (XXI)" hyperlink).<br />

2. See Welcome to the UNCITRAL Web Site, http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/welcome.html (last<br />

visited on May 24, 2007) (describing its mission as: "The core legal body of the United Nations system in<br />

the field of international trade law. A legal body with universal membership specializing in commercial law<br />

reform worldwide for over 40 years. UNCITRAL's business is the modernization and harmonization of<br />

rules on international business.").<br />

3. G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1, pt. I (stating that the General Assembly "[d]ecides to establish<br />

a United Nations Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong> . . . , which shall have for its object the<br />

promotion of the progressive harmonization and unification of the law of international trade.<br />

4. In establishing UNCITRAL, the General Assembly stated:<br />

Considering that international trade co-operation among <strong>State</strong>s is an important factor in the<br />

promotion of friendly relations and, consequently, in the maintenance of peace and security,<br />

Recalling its belief that the interests of all peoples, and particularly those of developing<br />

countries, demand the betterment of conditions favouring the extensive development of<br />

international trade,<br />

Reaffirming its conviction that divergencies arising from the laws of different <strong>State</strong>s in matters<br />

relating to international trade constitute one of the obstacles to the development of world<br />

trade.<br />

G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1.<br />

5. In its website, UNCITRAL defines the terms harmonization and unification in this way:<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 476 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

legislation, involving the identification of common approaches among existing<br />

domestic laws. Reports to the General Assembly and the Commission in the late<br />

1960s suggest that international actors understood the "progressive harmonization<br />

and unification" of trade law as involving the reconciliation of divergent practices<br />

and an articulation of emerging international norms. Current statements of<br />

UNCITRAL's efforts in achieving the "modernization and harmonization" of trade<br />

law depict UNCITRAL as a more pro-active participant in the reform of global<br />

commercial law. This version of international law reform-which looks to<br />

modernize, rather than simply harmonize, national laws-can come with one of two<br />

purposes. Where technical or market developments have outstripped existing law<br />

and the lack of suitable regulation is viewed by the international community to stall<br />

commercial development, modernization would require an (international)<br />

organization to create new law. With this relatively new method of modernization,<br />

the global actor purports to speak authoritatively to national legislatures about both<br />

the need for and content of law. Modernization may threaten national legislatures'<br />

sovereignty more acutely than an "in with the new" reform agenda where national<br />

law exists on a topic, but is viewed by the international community as out-of-date.<br />

This "out with the old" method of modernization requires the international<br />

organization both to reject existing legislation and create new law, whereas "in with<br />

the new" modernization requires simply the filling of a gap in the old law with new<br />

law. In either case, modernization might work against harmonization or unification<br />

since "modernization" presumably relates to a revision of the law to meet new<br />

exigencies, revisions that might not be consistent with existing national laws or<br />

global norms.'<br />

Both "in with the new" and "out with the old" modernization challenge<br />

traditional concepts of international law and law reform, and with this challenge<br />

"Harmonization" and "unification" of the law of international trade refers to the process<br />

through which the law facilitating international commerce is created and adopted.<br />

International commerce may be hindered by factors such as the lack of a predictable governing<br />

law or out-of-date laws unsuited to commercial practice. The United Nations Commission on<br />

International Trade <strong>Law</strong> identifies such problems and then carefully crafts solutions which are<br />

acceptable to <strong>State</strong>s having different legal systems and levels of economic and social<br />

development.<br />

"Harmonization" may conceptually be thought of as the process through which domestic laws<br />

may be modified to enhance predictability in cross-border commercial transactions.<br />

"Unification" may be seen as the adoption by <strong>State</strong>s of a common legal standard governing<br />

particular aspects of international business transactions. A model law or a legislative guide is<br />

an example of a text which is drafted to harmonize domestic law, while a convention is an<br />

international instrument which is adopted by <strong>State</strong>s for the unification of the law at an<br />

international level. Texts resulting from the work of UNCITRAL include conventions, model<br />

laws, legal guides, legislative guides, rules, and practice notes. In practice, the two concepts are<br />

closely related.<br />

FAQ - Origin, Mandate and Composition of UNCITRAL,<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/about/originjfaq.html (last visited May 24, 2007).<br />

6. Frequently, of course, "modernization" is a euphemism for adaptation of a weaker country's laws<br />

in the direction of a powerful sovereign state or international organization that has the cultural authority to<br />

define the meaning of "modern." This implies that modernization might either take the form of a<br />

functional adaptation of law to new circumstances, or the form of cultural conformity with a powerful<br />

symbolic standard promulgated by a "modernizing" global institution, or both.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 477 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

comes an impetus for new tools. Because uniformity may not be necessary to (and<br />

may, in some cases, undermine) the goal of modernization, there is room to question<br />

whether law reform projects intending to modernize the law of international trade<br />

should rely on international instruments meant to produce a single, uniform legal<br />

standard.<br />

UNCITRAL has predominantly relied on conventions and model laws to reach<br />

agreement on international instruments promoting international trade. A<br />

convention takes the form of a multilateral treaty. Countries accede to a single<br />

standard. As a result, the demands for accession are high since countries may not<br />

alter any part of the convention to suit domestic political or legal differences.<br />

Likewise, conditions of formulation require zero-sum bargaining in order to reach<br />

agreement. Both conditions mean that conventions are more likely to succeed<br />

where agreement across radically different legal families and levels of economic<br />

development is possible. 7 Those conditions further imply that the politics of<br />

formulation and implementation will be time-consuming and the prospects of<br />

subsequent adaptation prohibitive.<br />

A model law relaxes some of the strictures of conventions. 8 It takes the form of<br />

a legislative text that UNCITRAL recommends for enactment. However, in order<br />

to be responsive to the particular needs of a given state, a model law may implicitly<br />

permit states to exclude or modify some provisions. 9 While a model law sets a global<br />

standard, neither its conditions of formulation are as demanding nor its conditions of<br />

implementation as severe as a convention. ° As a result-although it appears as a<br />

less harmonizing instrument than a convention-it may permit a higher threshold in<br />

the standard itself and encourage a greater number of countries to adopt a form of<br />

it." As an enhancement on a model law, UNCITRAL has coupled a model law with<br />

a guide to enactment that sets out background information, explanations of decisions,<br />

and information on various policy options that might enable legislators to make<br />

informed decisions. 2<br />

7. One senior official of UNCITRAL stated: "ITIhe realities of many subjects are that you couldn't<br />

do a convention on them." Interview by Terence Halliday with 4003 (Aug. 9, 2002) (unpublished<br />

interview, on file with authors) [hereinafter Interview 4003].<br />

8. See UNCITRAL, Working Group on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, Working Paper: Possible Future Work on<br />

Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, paras. 162-68, U.N. Doc. A/CN.9/WG.V/WP.50 (Sept. 20, 1999) [hereinafter<br />

UNCITRAL, Possible Future Work on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>].<br />

9. It permits it by default because international model laws can only recommend; they cannot<br />

prescribe. By contrast, it is impossible to sign on to only portions of a convention.<br />

10. There are also variations in the form of model laws. Contrast the Model <strong>Law</strong> on International<br />

Commercial Arbitration, which is a procedural instrument with tightly linked inter-dependent articles, and<br />

the Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Commerce, which offers sets of principles with potential variations for<br />

satisfying them. UNCITRAL, Possible Future Work on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 8, paras. 165-66. A<br />

former Secretary of UNCITRAL observes that the Model <strong>Law</strong> on Arbitration now covers approximately<br />

one third of the world, something that would have been impossible with a convention. Interview 4003,<br />

supra note 7.<br />

11. In practice, UNCITRAL observes that "[d]eviations from the Model <strong>Law</strong> text have, as a rule, very<br />

rarely been made by countries adopting enacting legislation, suggesting that it has been widely accepted as<br />

a coherent model text." UNCITRAL, Possible Future Work on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 8, para. 165.<br />

This is something of an overstatement-scholars and practitioners agree that various countries' legislation<br />

to implement the Model <strong>Law</strong> on Cross Border Insolvencies have varied in how true the provisions of the<br />

implementing legislation have been to the terms of the Model <strong>Law</strong>.<br />

12. Id. para. 164.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 478 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

Whatever the merits of conventions and model laws for the inducement of<br />

unification or harmonization, UNCITRAL has also historically understood the need<br />

for flexibility, diplomacy and patience in its law reform projects and the potential<br />

inflexibility of uniformity as a goal of global law reform. Because conventions can<br />

limit drafters' room to maneuver, lead to the exclusion of issues on which delegates<br />

cannot reach consensus or, worse still, be conducive to reliance on compromise<br />

language that leaves an issue either unresolved or muddier than before, international<br />

conventions may not provide the best route toward modernization. While model<br />

laws are generally viewed as softer tools in the hands of international reformers than<br />

conventions, they too may possess an appearance of completeness and intractability.<br />

Cognizant of these trade-offs, as UNCITRAL has shifted its focus toward<br />

modernization it has invented new legal technologies-guides to enactment,<br />

recommendations, model legal provisions, and legislative guides-that offer greater<br />

flexibility to reform a broader range of laws, especially with the benefit of time and<br />

incremental progress. 3 Indeed, the implementation of this more expansive mission<br />

could only have proceeded on the basis of a broader repertoire of legal<br />

technologies.' 4<br />

This shift in goals through the invention of technologies is well illustrated by<br />

UNCITRAL's work on the Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>." 3 Although many<br />

experts were pessimistic about the prospect of a legislative guide on insolvency, the<br />

UN General Assembly confounded their expectations and ratified a Legislative<br />

Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> in December 2004.16 How did UNCITRAL succeed in<br />

promulgating the Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>? 7 How did its reliance on a<br />

legislative guide, rather than a convention or model law, enable the UNCITRAL's<br />

Working Group on Insolvency to produce global rules on insolvency law? In this<br />

article," we argue that by inventing a new legal technology UNCITRAL was able to<br />

join specific recommendations with lengthy and nuanced commentary intended to<br />

13. Other scholars have argued the UNCITRAL acts "incrementally" and count this incrementalism<br />

as among its strengths. The term was first employed by John Pottow. See John A.E. Pottow, Procedural<br />

Incrementalism: A Model for International Bankruptcy, 45 VA. J. INT'L L. 935 (2005) (describing<br />

UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong> on Cross Border Insolvency as fundamentally procedural in focus and describing<br />

merits of process of incremental proceduralism).<br />

14. By "social technologies," social scientists refer to systematic social means of achieving a particular<br />

outcome. A legal technology is simply a social technology adapted to and employed in the legal arena. See<br />

Terence C. Halliday, Legitimacy, Technology, and Leverage: The Building Blocks of Insolvency<br />

Architecture in the Decade Past and the Decade Ahead, 33 BROOK. J. INT'L L. (forthcoming 2007).<br />

15. UNCITRAL, LEGISLATIVE GUIDE ON INSOLVENCY LAW, U.N. Sales No. E.05V.10 (2005)<br />

[hereinafter Insolvency Guide], available at http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/insolven/05-<br />

80722_Ebook.pdf.<br />

16. Id. at iii.<br />

17. Not all share our opinion that UNCITRAL has succeeded in this arena. See, e.g., Clayton P.<br />

Gillette & Robert E. Scott, The Political Economy of International Sales <strong>Law</strong>, 25 INT'L REV. L. & ECON.<br />

446 (2005) (expressing skepticism about the necessity and desirability of efforts to unify and harmonize<br />

laws governing international commerce); Paul B. Stephan, The Futility of Unification and Harmonization in<br />

International Commercial <strong>Law</strong>, 39 VA. J. INT'L L. 743 (1999) (decrying wisdom of UNCITRAL's quest for<br />

global harmonization in commercial law as wrong-headed).<br />

18. This Article builds on a companion work in which we argue that UNCITRAL's success as an<br />

agent of global law reform follows from its unique claim to legitimacy among international actors given its<br />

representativeness and consensual decisionmaking. See Susan Block-Lieb & Terence C. Halliday,<br />

Legitimation and Global <strong>Law</strong>making (Fordham <strong>Law</strong> Legal Studies Research Paper No. 952492, 2006),<br />

available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfmabstract-id=952492.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 479 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

educate domestic legislatures. In addition, by inventing an array of rule-types within<br />

the recommendations made in the legislative guide, UNCITRAL enabled the<br />

Working Group to speak authoritatively and in great detail on a range of topics, but<br />

on other issues to say little in deference to social and political concerns. In short,<br />

UNCITRAL succeeded in this arena by embracing its diplomacy as a strength and<br />

not a weakness.<br />

Our examination of UNCITRAL's Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong><br />

demonstrates that modernization may come at a price. A legislative guide is on its<br />

face less harmonizing than a model law, just as a model law is on its face less<br />

harmonizing than a convention. Nonetheless, we argue that less is more, at least in<br />

this instance. Many in the Insolvency Working Group believed that it would have<br />

been impossible to achieve a convention or a model law on insolvency law.<br />

UNCITRAL consciously decided to rely on a legislative guide to structure its work<br />

principally because the flexibility of this technology took away the need to reach<br />

consensus on myriad details, and more importantly, the contentious policy issues<br />

inherent in such an endeavor. UNCITRAL created a legal technology purporting to<br />

require less harmonization because it viewed the flexibility of a legislative guide as<br />

increasing the likelihood that it would succeed in promulgating an international<br />

instrument on domestic insolvency law.<br />

This is not to deny that the Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> might have a<br />

harmonizing effect. Nor should we view UNCITRAL's reliance on technologies<br />

other than conventions and model laws as an abandonment of the desirability of<br />

promoting the "progressive harmonization and unification" of trade law.<br />

Harmonization takes time, and global law reform involves the efforts of both<br />

international and domestic actors. Because national actors may not feel<br />

international pressure to adopt the recommendations in a legislative guide<br />

wholesale, they can feel free to adopt what they can. With a convention or model<br />

law, accession or implementing legislation may fail precisely because the choices are<br />

binary-either accept it in its entirety or reject it outright. A legislative guide offers<br />

national actors choices, albeit within limits. The decision to promulgate a legislative<br />

guide might in practice result in greater harmonization "on the ground" than a<br />

model law or convention. 9<br />

The remainder of this Article is organized as follows. Part I briefly traces the<br />

organizational development of UNCITRAL and demonstrates that UNCITRAL<br />

broadened its mission over time to include not just the harmonization of<br />

international commercial law but also its modernization. This Part finds that, in the<br />

course of more broadly defining its core mission, UNCITRAL also broadened the<br />

range of international instruments it relied upon to accomplish law reform, and that<br />

the breadth of mission and technologies are inter-related. Part II focuses on<br />

UNCITRAL's most recent project-the Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>-and<br />

compares and contrasts it with UNCITRAL's earlier work. This Part describes this<br />

new legal technology-a legislative guide-as combining legislative<br />

recommendations with commentary. The commentary justifies the<br />

recommendations made in the Guide in terms of the policy purposes of the<br />

provisions; where recommendations are more open-ended, the commentary assists<br />

legislatures with the Herculean task of assessing the choices that remain. We<br />

19. In part, this may occur because a guide has greater legitimacy-both formulated by a global quasilegislature<br />

and adopted by a national legislature. See id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 480 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

conclude that the array of linguistic forms in which the recommendations were<br />

expressed in the Guide gave UNCITRAL the flexibility to adjust its level of<br />

prescription to the level of consensus it could achieve and, as a result, the flexibility<br />

to modernize insolvency law. Part III turns back to the apparent tension between<br />

modernization (at least the "out with the old" variety) and UNCITRAL's original<br />

mission: the "progressive harmonization and unification" of trade law. We argue<br />

that UNCITRAL's pursuit of the modernization of the law of international trade<br />

should not be viewed as inconsistent with the goals of "harmonization and<br />

unification;" instead, UNCITRAL has adapted its implementation of the goals of<br />

harmonization and unification in recognition of pragmatic limitations that inhere in<br />

(second order) international lawmaking. In Part IV, we conclude that UNCITRAL's<br />

adoption of modernization as a goal both expands its organizational reach and<br />

demands technologies that will underwrite its expansive aspirations.<br />

I. UNIFICATION, HARMONIZATION, AND MODERNIZATION<br />

The United Nation's General Assembly adopted a resolution to establish its<br />

Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong> in 1966. In justifying the creation of<br />

UNCITRAL, the General Assembly "[r]eafflrm[ed] its conviction that divergencies<br />

arising from the laws of different <strong>State</strong>s in matters relating to international trade<br />

constitute one of the obstacles to the development of world trade." 2 " Thus, the<br />

decision to establish a Commission, "which shall have for its object the promotion of<br />

the progressive harmonization and unification of the law of international trade," was<br />

based on a belief that "the extensive development of international trade" could best<br />

be furthered by removing "divergencies arising from the laws of different <strong>State</strong>s"-<br />

by harmonizing and unifying the law of international trade through "promoting the<br />

adoption of international conventions, uniform laws, standard contract provisions,<br />

general conditions of sale, standard trade terms and other measures."'" The<br />

harmonization and unification of the law of trade was sought on the presumption<br />

that it enabled international trade and not simply for the sake of harmonizing and<br />

unifying laws. International trade was said to favor "the interests of all peoples" and<br />

"particularly those of developing countries" because "international trade cooperation<br />

among <strong>State</strong>s is an important factor in the promotion<br />

2<br />

of friendly relations<br />

and, consequently, in the maintenance of peace and security.<br />

Over time, UNCITRAL has pursued its mission of the "progressive<br />

harmonization and unification" of trade law with a pragmatic vision of its primary<br />

purpose-the promotion of international trade. UNCITRAL is probably best<br />

known for its drafting of the Convention on Contracts for the International Sales of<br />

Goods, 23 which has been adopted in nearly seventy countries including the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s." Over the past forty years, UNCITRAL has produced conventions, model<br />

20. G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1.<br />

21. Id.<br />

22. Id.<br />

23. United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods, Apr. 11, 1980, S.<br />

Treaty Doc. No. 98-9. 1489 U.N.T.S. 59, available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/sales/cisg/CISG.pdf.<br />

24. For a list of the roughly seventy nations that have adopted the United Nations Convention on<br />

Contracts for the International Sale of Goods (CISG) in one form or another, see Status, 1980 - United<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 481 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

laws, legislative guides and other international instruments on many areas of<br />

procedural and substantive law, including international arbitration, 2 5 e-commerce, 2 6<br />

international payments, 27 procurement, and infrastructure development, 8<br />

international transport of goods, 29 and insolvency. 0 There currently are six active<br />

Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods,<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/uncitral-texts/sale-goods/1980CISG-status.html (last visited May 26,<br />

2007). Neither Japan nor the United Kingdom has adopted the CISG.<br />

25. See, e.g., UNCITRAL Arbitration Rules, 15 I.L.M. 701 (1976), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/arbitration/arb-rules/arb-rules.pdf; UNCITRAL Conciliation<br />

Rules, G.A. Res. 35/52, U.N. GAOR, 35th Sess., Supp. No. 48, U.N. Doc. A/35/52 (July 23, 1980), available<br />

at http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/arbitration/conc-rules/conc-rules-e.pdf; Recommendations to<br />

Assist Arbitral Institutions and Other Interested Bodies with Regard to Arbitrations Under the UNCITRAL<br />

Arbitration Rules, 1982 Y.B. Int'l Trade L. Comm'n 420, U.N. Sales No. E.84.V.5, available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/arbitration/arb-recommendation/arb-recommendation-e.pdf;<br />

UNCITRAL: Model <strong>Law</strong> on International Commercial Arbitration, 24 I.L.M. 1302 (1985), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdflenglish/texts/arbitration/m-arb/06-54671-Ebook.pdf; UNCITRAL Notes on<br />

Organizing Arbitral Proceedings, U.N. GAOR, 29th Sess., Supp. No. 17, U.N. Doc. A/51/17 (1996),<br />

available at http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/arbitration/arb-notes/arb-notes-e.pdf; UNCITRAL<br />

MODEL LAW ON INTERNATIONAL COMMERCIAL CONCILIATION WITH GUIDE TO ENACTMENT AND USE,<br />

U.N. Sales No. E.05.V.4 (2002), available at http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/arbitration/mlconc/ml-conc-e.pdf.<br />

26. UNCITRAL Recommendation on the Legal Value of Computer Records (1985), available at,<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdflenglish/texts/electcom/computerrecords-e.pdf; UNCITRAL MODEL LAW ON<br />

ELECTRONIC COMMERCE WITH GUIDE TO ENACTMENT, U.N. Sales No. E.99.V.4 (1996), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/electcom/05-89450_Ebook.pdf; UNCITRAL MODEL LAW ON<br />

ELECTRONIC SIGNATURES WITH GUIDE TO ENACTMENT, U.N. Sales No. E.02.V.8 (2001), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdflenglish/texts/electcom/ml-elecsig-e.pdf; United Nations Convention on the Use<br />

of Electronic Communications in International Contracts, G.A. Res. 60/21, U.N. GAOR, 60th Sess., Supp.<br />

No. 49, U.N. Doc. A/RES/60/21 (Dec. 6, 2005), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/electcom/06-57452_Ebook.pdf.<br />

27. United Nations Convention on International Bills of Exchange and International Promissory<br />

Notes, Dec. 9, 1988, 28 I.L.M. 177 (1989), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/payments/billsnotes/X_12_e.pdf; UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong> on<br />

International Credit Transfers, 32 I.L.M. 587 (1992), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/payments/transfers/mi-credittrans.pdf; United Nations<br />

Convention on Independent Guarantees and Stand-by Letters of Credit, Dec. 11, 1995, 2169 U.N.T.S. 190,<br />

35 I.L.M. 735, available at http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/payments/guarantees/guarantees.pdf;<br />

United Nations Convention on the Assignment of Receivables in International Trade, Dec. 12, 2001, G.A.<br />

Res. 56/81, U.N. GAOR, 56th Sess., U.N. Doc. A[RES/56/81 (2002), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/payments/receivables/ctc-assignment-convention-e.pdf.<br />

28. UNCITRAL LEGAL GUIDE ON DRAWING UP INTERNATIONAL CONTRACTS FOR THE<br />

CONSTRUCTION OF INDUSTRIAL WORKS, U.N. Doc. A/CN.9/SER.B/2, U.N. Sales No. E.87.V.10 (1987),<br />

available at http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/procurem/construction/Igconstr-e.pdf; UNCITRAL<br />

Model <strong>Law</strong> on Procurement of Goods and Construction with Guide to Enactment (1993), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/procurem/proc93/proc93.pdf; UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong> on<br />

Procurement of Goods, Construction and Services, with Guide to Enactment, U.N. Doc. AICN.9/403 (1994),<br />

available at http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/procurem/ml-procurement/m-procure.pdf;<br />

UNCITRAL LEGISLATIVE GUIDE ON PRIVATELY FINANCED INFRASTRUCTURE PROJECTS, U.N. Doc.<br />

A/CN.9/SER.B/4, U.N. Sales No. E.01.V.4 (2000), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/procurem/pfip/guide/pfip-e.pdf; MODEL LEGISLATIVE<br />

PROVISIONS ON PRIVATELY FINANCED INFRASTRUCTURE PROJECTS, U.N. Sales No. E.04.V.11 (2003),<br />

available at http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/procurem/pfip/model/annexl-e.pdf.<br />

29. United Nations Convention on the Carriage of Goods by Sea, Mar. 31, 1978, 1695 U.N.T.S. 3, 17<br />

I.L.M. 608, available at http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/transport/hamburg/Xl-d-3-e.pdf (referred<br />

to as the Hamburg Rules); Unit of Account Provision and Provisions for the Adjustment of the Limit of<br />

Liability in International Transport and Liability Conventions (1982); United Nations Convention on the<br />

Liability of Operators of Transport Terminals in International Trade, Apr. 19, 1991, 30 I.L.M. 1503,<br />

available at http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/transport/ott/X_13-e.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 482 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

UNCITRAL working groups, whose topics range from insolvency 3 and secured<br />

transactions 32 to electronic commerce, procurement, transport law, and international<br />

arbitration and conciliation 3 Consistent with its mandate to coordinate legal<br />

activities among international organizations working in the field of international<br />

trade law,- UNCITRAL also partners loosely from time to time with entities such as<br />

the Hague Convention, the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund<br />

(IMF) for the drafting and implementation of core areas of commercial law in<br />

transitional and developing countries. 3<br />

Table 1 lists UNCITRAL's work product over time. It also lists the legal<br />

technologies UNCITRAL employed for these projects. Table 1 demonstrates that<br />

UNCITRAL has historically relied on model laws and conventions to communicate<br />

to domestic legislatures. Over time, it has adopted two sets of rules, seven<br />

conventions, two recommendations, two sets of model legal provisions, eight model<br />

laws (four of which it combined with guides to enactment), one legal guide and one<br />

set of notes. Of the twenty-five international instruments produced by UNCITRAL<br />

since its inception, fifteen constitute model laws or conventions. When we focus<br />

exclusively on legal technologies directed to domestic legislatures and other public<br />

audiences, however, these technologies nearly uniformly have taken the form of<br />

conventions, model laws or model legal provisions (with three exceptions). On this<br />

ground, we exclude UNCITRAL's product on arbitration and conciliation from the<br />

count, since these media are directed to private parties, including international<br />

arbitrators, rather than domestic legislatures. Similarly, we exclude UNCITRAL's<br />

Legal Guide on Drawing Up International Contracts for the Construction of<br />

Industrial Works for nearly the same reason: it is directed to contracting parties,<br />

although in this case the intended audience includes both private parties and<br />

government agencies drafting construction contracts with an international focus.<br />

When it has spoken to domestic legislatures, UNCITRAL has overwhelmingly<br />

chosen to speak through conventions (of which it has produced seven), model laws<br />

(of which there are eight) and model legal provisions (of which there exist two sets).<br />

The only exceptions to this general observation include one recommendation (on the<br />

30. UNCITRAL, UNCITRAL MODEL LAW ON CROSs-BORDER INSOLVENCY WITH GUIDE TO<br />

ENACTMENT, U.N. Sales No. E.99.V.3 (1997), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/insolven/insolvency-e.pdf; see also INSOLVENCY GUIDE, supra<br />

note 15.<br />

31. For a list and description of the ongoing work of the Insolvency Working Group, see Working<br />

Group V, http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/commission/working__groups/51nsolvency.html (last visited<br />

June 4, 2007).<br />

32. The Working Group on Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong> began its work on the Secured Transactions<br />

Guide in 2000 and projects the guide's completion in late 2007. For a list and description of the ongoing<br />

work of the Secured Transactions Working Group, see Working Group VI,<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/commission/working-groups/6Security-Interests.html (last visited June<br />

4, 2007).<br />

33. For a description of Working Groups I, II, III, and IV and their ongoing projects and draft work<br />

product, see Working Groups, http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/commission/working-groups.html (last<br />

visited June 4, 2007).<br />

34. G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1.<br />

35. For a description of UNCITRAL's coordination with other international organizations, see<br />

Coordination of Work on International Trade <strong>Law</strong>,<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/tac/coordination.html (last visited June 4, 2007).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 483 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL VOL. 42:475<br />

Legal Value of Computer Records) and two legislative guides (one on Privately<br />

Financed Infrastructure Projects and another on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>).<br />

UNCITRAL's reliance on conventions, model laws and model legal provisions<br />

seem well matched with its core mission to produce "the progressive harmonization<br />

and unification of the law of international trade." 36 Conventions necessarily unify<br />

the law that a convention covers, at least for those nations who accede to it; where<br />

numerous countries agree to be bound by the terms of the convention, the<br />

unification of law follows a broad path. Model laws can have similarly unifying<br />

effects, although only where national legislatures implement the model law<br />

provisions by adopting domestic legislation that closely tracks the model law. 7<br />

Because model laws are not self-executing in that they depend upon national<br />

legislatures to adopt implementing legislation for their effectiveness, they intrude<br />

less on national sovereignty. 38 In permitting national legislatures greater freedom to<br />

adjust the model law provisions to local social and political demands, model laws risk<br />

non-uniformity. 39 Where implementing legislation differs only in small ways from<br />

the model law, however, the distinction between a convention and a model law<br />

pertains not so much to the uniformity of the resulting legal rules but to the number<br />

of countries who agree to be bound.' The assumption is that fewer nations will sign<br />

and ratify a convention, given the lack of flexibility on its terms, than will support<br />

UNCITRAL's promulgation of a model law and adopt their own implementing<br />

legislation.<br />

36. G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1, pt. I.<br />

8. The Commission shall further the progressive harmonization and unification of the law of<br />

international trade by:<br />

(c) Preparing or promoting the adoption of new international conventions, model laws and<br />

uniform laws and promoting the codification and wider acceptance of international trade terms,<br />

provisions, customs and practices, in collaboration, where appropriate, with the organizations<br />

operating in this field....<br />

G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1, para. 8.<br />

37. For a similar statement of the relationship between unification and conventions, harmonization,<br />

and model laws, see FAQ - Origin, Mandate and Composition of UNCITRAL, supra note 5 ("A model<br />

law or a legislative guide is an example of a text which is drafted to harmonize domestic law, while a<br />

convention is an international instrument which is adopted by <strong>State</strong>s for the unification of the law at an<br />

international level.").<br />

38. UNCITRAL's secretariat describes a model law in the following terms:<br />

A model law is a legislative text that is recommended to <strong>State</strong>s for adoption as part of their<br />

national law. In incorporating the text of the model law in its system, a <strong>State</strong> may tailor the text<br />

of the law to its needs and, if appropriate, modify or leave out some of its provisions.<br />

UNCITRAL, Possible Future Work on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 8, para. 162.<br />

39. See id. para. 162-63 ("A model law is an appropriate vehicle for modernization and unification of<br />

national laws when it is expected that <strong>State</strong>s will wish or need to make adjustments to the uniform text to<br />

accommodate local requirements that vary from system to system, or where strict uniformity is not<br />

necessary.").<br />

40. In some instances, UNCITRAL understood from the promulgation of a model law that <strong>State</strong>s<br />

would deviate from the text of the model. See UNCITRAL, Possible Future Work on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>,<br />

supra note 8, paras. 165-66.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 484 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

TABLE 1. UNCITRAL WORK PRODUCTS AND LEGAL TECHNOLOGIES,<br />

1976-2005<br />

Year UNCITRAL Work Product Legal Technology<br />

1974 Convention on the Limitations Convention<br />

Period in the International Sales of<br />

Goods<br />

1976 Arbitration Rules Rules<br />

1978 Convention on the Carriage of Convention<br />

Goods by Sea (the "Hamburg<br />

Rules")<br />

1980 Conciliation Rules Rules<br />

1980 Convention on Contracts for the Convention<br />

International Sale of Goods<br />

1982 Recommendations to assist arbitral Recommendations<br />

institutions and other interested<br />

bodies with regard to arbitrations<br />

under the UNCITRAL Arbitration<br />

Rules<br />

1982 Unit of Account Provision and Model legislative provisions<br />

Provisions for the Adjustment of the<br />

Limit of Liability in International<br />

Transport and Liability Conventions<br />

1983 Uniform Rules on Contract Clauses Rules<br />

for an Agreed Sum Due to Failure of<br />

Performance<br />

1985 Model <strong>Law</strong> on International Model law<br />

Commercial Arbitration<br />

1985 Recommendation on the Legal Recommendation<br />

Value of Computer Records<br />

1987 Legal Guide on Drawing Up Legal guide<br />

International Contracts for the<br />

Construction of Industrial Works<br />

1988 Convention on International Bills of Convention<br />

Exchange and International<br />

Promissory Notes<br />

1991 Convention on the Liability of Convention<br />

Operators of Transport Terminals in<br />

International Trade<br />

1992 Model <strong>Law</strong> on International Credit Model law<br />

Transfers<br />

1992 Legal Guide on International Legal guide<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 485 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

Counter-Trade Transactions<br />

1993 Model <strong>Law</strong> on Procurement of Model law + guide to<br />

Goods and Construction with Guide<br />

enactment<br />

to Enactment<br />

1994 Model <strong>Law</strong> on Procurement of Model law + guide to<br />

Goods, Construction and Services,<br />

enactment<br />

with Guide to Enactment<br />

1995 Convention on Independent Convention<br />

Guarantees and Stand-by Letters of<br />

Credit<br />

1996 Notes on Organizing Arbitral Notes<br />

Proceedings<br />

1996 Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Commerce Model law + guide to<br />

with Guide to Enactment<br />

enactment<br />

1997 Model <strong>Law</strong> on Cross-Border Model law + guide to<br />

Insolvency with Guide to Enactment<br />

enactment<br />

2000 Legislative Guide on Privately Legislative guide<br />

Financed Infrastructure Projects<br />

2001 Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Signatures Model law + guide to<br />

with Guide to Enactment<br />

enactment<br />

2001 Convention on the Assignment of Convention<br />

Receivables in International Trade<br />

2002 Model <strong>Law</strong> on International Model law + guide to<br />

Commercial Conciliation with Guide enactment and use<br />

to Enactment and Use<br />

2003 Model Legislative Provisions on Model legislative provisions<br />

Privately Financed Infrastructure<br />

Projects<br />

2005 Convention on the Use of Electronic Convention<br />

Communications in International<br />

Contracts<br />

2005 Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> Legislative guide<br />

Table 1 also demonstrates that conventions and model laws retain importance<br />

even today, evidencing UNCITRAL's continued commitment to the goals of<br />

unification and harmonization. UNCITRAL promulgated six conventions between<br />

1978 and 2005. 41 Its reliance on model laws is also evenly spread over time; between<br />

1982 and 2003, UNCITRAL adopted ten model laws or model legislative<br />

provisions." Table 1 does not, however, demonstrate any obvious correlation<br />

between whether UNCITRAL chose to rely on a convention or model law and the<br />

subject matter of the instrument. Every Working Group has produced at least one<br />

model law. UNCITRAL was most likely to rely on conventions when international<br />

41. See supra Table 1 (listing conventions promulgated by UNCITRAL during that time period).<br />

42. Id. (listing model laws developed by UNCITRAL during that time period).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 486 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

transport of goods 3 and international payments" were the topic, but there are also<br />

conventions regarding electronic commerce 5 and the international sales of goods. 46<br />

Indeed, since 2000, UNCITRAL's work has been fairly evenly divided between<br />

conventions (2), model laws (3) and legislative guides (2).<br />

When we look at UNCITRAL's ongoing work, we see a similar pattern. There<br />

are six Working Groups, five of which met during 2006 and 2007. Working Groups<br />

I, 1I, and III are engaged in revisions to an earlier UNCITRAL model law or<br />

convention. Working Group I (procurement and project finance) continues to meet<br />

to discuss possible revisions to the UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong> on Procurement of<br />

Goods, Construction and Services. 8 Working Group II (international arbitration<br />

and conciliation) actively is considering revisions to the UNCITRAL Arbitration<br />

Rules. 49 Moreover, in its meeting in June and July of 2006, the Commission adopted<br />

amendments to the Model <strong>Law</strong> on International Commercial Arbitration that<br />

Working Group II had approved in its earlier meetings: ° Working Group III<br />

(transport law) is engaged in a review of a draft convention on the carriage of goods<br />

by sea." Only Working Groups V (insolvency) and VI (secured transactions) are not<br />

working on revisions to a model law or convention. The Secured Transaction<br />

Working Group has been working steadily since 2000 on its Legislative Guide on<br />

Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong>, with its work projected to be complete by some time in<br />

2007 or 2008.2 Following ratification of its Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> by<br />

the Commission and the UN's General Assembly, UNCITRAL directed the<br />

Insolvency Working Group to consider three additional topics: the treatment of<br />

corporate groups, particularly in cross-border insolvency proceedings; financing of<br />

cross-border insolvency proceedings; and court-to-court communication and the use<br />

of protocols in cross-border insolvency proceedings. 3<br />

43. See supra note 29 (listing UNCITRAL conventions dealing with the international transport of<br />

goods).<br />

44. See supra note 27 (indicating that there are three conventions and one model law on the topic of<br />

international payments).<br />

45. See supra note 26 (indicating that UNCITRAL has promulgated one convention concerning<br />

electronic commerce).<br />

46. See United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods, supra note 23.<br />

47. See supra Table 1 (listing conventions, model laws, and legislative guides created by<br />

UNCITRAL). This does not count work in progress, and so does not include ongoing work on the<br />

Legislative Guide on Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong>, for example.<br />

48. For a description of UNCITRAL's ongoing work on procurement, see Working Group I,<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/uncitrallen/commissionlworking-groups/lProcurement.html (last visited June 4,<br />

2007).<br />

49. For a description of UNCITRAL's ongoing work on arbitration, see Working Group II,<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/commission/working-groups/2Arbitration.html (last visited June 4,<br />

2007).<br />

50. Id.<br />

51. For a description of the UNCITRAL's ongoing work on transport law, see Working Group III,<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/uncitrallen/commissionlworking__groups/3Transport.html (last visited June 4, 2007).<br />

52. See G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1.<br />

53. For a description of the ongoing work of the Insolvency Working Group, see Working Group V,<br />

supra note 31. Despite having met twice, it remains unclear whether the Group conceives of its mandate as<br />

one to draft a legislative guide or other document.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 487 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

A. The Shift Toward Modernization<br />

What can be said about UNCITRAL's work that did not take the form of a<br />

convention or a model law but still was addressed to legislatures and national actors<br />

(rather than private parties)? For instance, what of the Recommendation on the<br />

Legal Value of Computer Records, promulgated by UNCITRAL in 1985? We view<br />

this Recommendation as UNCITRAL's first effort at modernizing the law of trade,<br />

and note that with this international instrument UNCITRAL walked very gingerly<br />

into the topic of automatic data processing, computer records and electronic<br />

communications. Comprising no more than two pages in length, it amounts to little<br />

more than a "Recommendation" to "Governments" that they review their "legal<br />

rules affecting the use of computer records as evidence in litigation in order to<br />

eliminate unnecessary obstacles to their admission," as well as any "legal<br />

requirements" that "trade related documents" or "documents for submission to<br />

governments" be "in writing" or signed." The preamble paragraphs of the<br />

Recommendation make clear that, although the commercial practices associated<br />

with electronic communications were rapidly changing, domestic commercial laws<br />

had not. 55 Because there were no existing domestic laws on the books, there was<br />

nothing particular to harmonize; instead, there was a sense that the technology was<br />

poised to mushroom in importance and a fear that international trade would be held<br />

back if commercial law was not brought up to speed with these commercial practices.<br />

The case for "in with the new" modernization was, thus, first made with this<br />

Recommendation.<br />

The concepts of electronic commerce and, indeed, of UNCITRAL as an agent<br />

of modernization, were so new that eleven years passed before UNCITRAL next<br />

spoke on the topic of the computerization of commercial practices, 6 but since then,<br />

UNCITRAL has promulgated two model laws and one convention on the topic 57 and<br />

54. UNCITRAL Recommendation on the Legal Value of Computer Records, supra note 26.<br />

55. Id. It reads:<br />

Noting that the use of automatic data processing (ADP) is about to become firmly established<br />

throughout the world in many phases of domestic and international trade as well as in<br />

administrative services, [and]<br />

Noting also that legal rules based upon pre-ADP paper-based means of documenting<br />

international trade may create an obstacle to such use of ADP in that they lead to legal<br />

insecurity or impede the efficient use of ADP where its use is otherwise justified ....<br />

Id.<br />

56. It may be unfair to say that UNCITRAL waited eleven years to speak on the topic of electronic<br />

communications. The Model <strong>Law</strong> on International Commercial Arbitration, promulgated in 1985, broadly<br />

defines a "writing" to include communications in an electronic format. UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong> on<br />

International Commercial Arbitration, supra note 25. Similarly, UNCITRAL's Legal Guide on Electronic<br />

Funds Transfers (1987) and Model <strong>Law</strong> on International Credit Transfers (1992) focused on the needs of<br />

electronic commerce. UNCITRAL LEGAL GUIDE ON ELECTRONIC FUNDS TRANSFERS, Sales No.<br />

E.87.V.9 (1987); UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong> on International Credit Transfers, supra note 27; see<br />

UNCITRAL MODEL LAW ON ELECTRONIC SIGNATURES WITH GUIDE TO ENACTMENT, supra note 26, at<br />

9 (discussing the background to the UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Signatures with Guide to<br />

Enactment).<br />

57. In 1996, UNCITRAL adopted a Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Commerce with Guide to Enactment;<br />

in 2001, it promulgated the Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Signatures with Guide to Enactment. UNCITRAL<br />

MODEL LAW ON ELECTRONIC COMMERCE WITH GUIDE TO ENACTMENT, supra note 26; UNCITRAL<br />

MODEL LAW ON ELECTRONIC SIGNATURES WITH GUIDE TO ENACTMENT, supra note 26. Most recently,<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 488 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

the term "modernization" is regularly employed with reference to these instruments<br />

and the topic of electronic communication and electronic commerce. For example,<br />

the UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Commerce explains its history and<br />

background as "prepared in response to a major change in the means by which<br />

communications are made between parties using computerized or other modern<br />

techniques in doing business" 58 and, thus, "to enhance the needed modernization of<br />

legislation." 59 The Guide to Enactment of the Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Commerce<br />

also employs the rhetoric of modernization, explaining the need both for the Model<br />

<strong>Law</strong> ° and for the accompanying Guide to Enactment 6 ' in terms of a need to<br />

modernize. Similarly, the UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Signatures notes,<br />

in its Guide to Enactment, that it "is designed to assist <strong>State</strong>s in establishing a<br />

modern, harmonized and fair legislative framework to address more effectively the<br />

issues of electronic signatures., 62 The United Nations Convention on the Use of<br />

Electronic Communications in International Contracts also justifies its need on the<br />

grounds that it "may help <strong>State</strong>s gain access to modern trade routes.""<br />

An interest in the modernization of trade law, including revisions to existing<br />

UNCITRAL product, currently dominates the Working Groups' work in progress<br />

and, frequently, the focus is on "in with the new" modernization intended to enable<br />

reliance on recent applications of electronic media to new industries. For example,<br />

among the reasons Working Group I (procurement and project finance) provides for<br />

its consideration of revisions to the Model <strong>Law</strong> on Procurement of Goods,<br />

Construction and Services is the need to add provisions in the Model <strong>Law</strong> addressing<br />

procurement by electronic means (for example, by email or over the Internet).<br />

Similarly, Working Group II (international arbitration and conciliation) proposed<br />

in 2005, the UN adopted its Convention on the Use of Electronic Communications in International<br />

Contracts. United Nations Convention on the Use of Electronic Communications in International<br />

Contracts, supra note 26; see supra Table I (listing the above provisions with dates of enactment).<br />

58. UNCITRAL MODEL LAW ON ELECTRONIC COMMERCE WITH GUIDE TO ENACTMENT, supra<br />

note 26, at 64.<br />

59. Id. at 67.<br />

60. Id. at 16 (describing the objectives of the Model <strong>Law</strong> as premised on the emergence of this<br />

"modern" technology: "The use of modern means of communication such as electronic mail and electronic<br />

data interchange (EDI) for the conduct of international trade transactions has been increasing rapidly and<br />

is expected to develop further as technical supports such as information highways and the INTERNET<br />

become more widely accessible."); id. at 64 (explaining the history and background of the Model <strong>Law</strong> as<br />

follows: "The Model <strong>Law</strong> is intended to serve as a model to countries for the evaluation and modernization<br />

of certain aspects of their laws and practices in the field of commercial relationships involving the use of<br />

computerized or other modern communication techniques, and for the establishment of relevant legislation<br />

where none presently exist.").<br />

61. Id. at 15 (explaining the need for a Guide to Enactment on the grounds that "the Model <strong>Law</strong><br />

would be a more effective tool for <strong>State</strong>s modernizing their legislation if background and explanatory<br />

information would be provided to executive branches of Governments and legislators to assist them in<br />

using the Model <strong>Law</strong>"). This Guide to Enactment also as much as admits harmonization had no role in its<br />

provisions. Id. at 16 ("While a few countries have adopted specific provisions to deal with certain aspects<br />

of electronic commerce, there exists no legislation dealing with electronic commerce as a whole.").<br />

62. UNCITRAL MODEL LAW ON ELECTRONIC SIGNATURES WITH GUIDE TO ENACTMENT, supra<br />

note 26, at 8.<br />

63. United Nations Convention on the Use of Electronic Communications in International Contracts,<br />

supra note 26, at 1, 25 ("Convinced that the adoption of uniform rules to remove obstacles to the use of<br />

electronic communications in international contracts, including obstacles that might result from the<br />

operation of existing international trade law instruments, would enhance legal certainty and commercial<br />

predictability for international contracts and help <strong>State</strong>s gain access to modern trade routes ... ").<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 489 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

amendments to the Model <strong>Law</strong> on International Commercial Arbitration and is<br />

considering revisions to UNCITRAL's Arbitration Rules partly to address issues<br />

raised by online dispute resolution. In addition, the work of Working Group III<br />

(international transport) on a draft convention on the carriage of goods by sea<br />

addresses, among other issues, questions regarding the validity and enforceability of<br />

electronic transportation documents.<br />

References to the need for modernization are not limited to "in with the new"<br />

modernization. In its 1999 report on Possible Future Work on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, the<br />

UNCITRAL Secretariat noted that an important justification for authorizing the<br />

Working Group on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> to begin its work on the Legislative Guide on<br />

Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> "was to modernize insolvency practices and laws. '' M With this<br />

reference, the term "modernization" took on a new meaning. Unlike UNCITRAL<br />

work to modernize commercial laws so that they reflect modern commercial<br />

practices involving electronic means of communication and commerce, the<br />

Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>s sought to "modernize insolvency practices<br />

and laws" by recommending to national actors that they replace their existing<br />

domestic insolvency laws with more modern ones. "Out with the old"<br />

modernization is not limited to insolvency reform. Similarly, a 2000 report on the<br />

then-current activities and possible future work of the Working Group on Secured<br />

Transactions justified authorizing it to begin work on the Legislative Guide on<br />

Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong> on the grounds that "modernization and optimization of<br />

secured credit law can lead to expanded economic development and, therefore,<br />

promote the general welfare., 6 1 In every year since 2000, the Commission's yearly<br />

report to the UN General Assembly reaffirms "its belief that the progressive<br />

modernization and harmonization of international trade law" both "reduce[es] or<br />

remov[es] legal obstacles to the flow of international trade" and "contribute[s]<br />

significantly to universal economic cooperation among all <strong>State</strong>s on a basis of<br />

equality, equity and common interest ....<br />

By now, UNCITRAL has incorporated the modernization of the law of<br />

international trade within its core mission. Although the term "modernization"<br />

nowhere appears in the UN Resolution establishing UNCITRAL, 67 UNCITRAL's<br />

mandate to "modernize" the law of international trade has become deeply ingrained<br />

in the ethos of the Commission - so much so that UNCITRAL describes its<br />

64. UNCITRAL, Possible Future Work on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 8, para. 2.<br />

65. UNCITRAL, Working Group on Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong>, Security Interests: Current Activities<br />

and Possible Future Work, para. 45, U.N. Doc. A/CN.9/475 (April 27, 2000) [hereinafter UNCITRAL,<br />

Security Interests], available at http http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/commission/sessions/33rd.html<br />

(follow "A/CN.9/475 - Security Interests - Current activities and possible future work" hyperlink).<br />

66. G.A. Res. 58/75, U.N. GAOR, 58th Sess., Supp. No. 17, U.N. Doc. A/RES/58/75 (Dec. 9, 2003),<br />

available at http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/GA/resolutions.html (follow "A/RES/58/75" hyperlink).<br />

Similar language appears in the General Assembly resolutions to adopt the Commission's reports on<br />

sessions between 2000 and 2005. The reference to "modernization" does not appear in reports pre-dating<br />

2000. The report reaffirms "its convictions that the progressive harmonization and unification of the law of<br />

international trade" would both "reduce[e] or remov[e] legal obstacles to the flow of international trade"<br />

and "contribute significantly to universal economic cooperation among all <strong>State</strong>s on a basis of equality...<br />

Id. For a complete list of these reports of the General Assembly, see General Assembly Resolutions,<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/GA/resolutions.html (last visited June 4, 2007).<br />

67. See G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1, pt. I (establishing a UN Commission "which shall have<br />

for its object the promotion of the progressive harmonization and unification of the law of international<br />

trade .... ). Perhaps the term "modernization" derives from emphasis on the need for "progressive"<br />

harmonization and unification of trade law.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 490 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

"business" as "the modernization and harmonization of rules on international<br />

business." '<br />

This focus on the modernization of the law of trade infuses more than<br />

UNCITRAL's substantive choices about what projects to adopt. It also affects the<br />

legal technologies through which UNCITRAL articulates its recommendations to<br />

domestic legislatures. The development of more flexible international technologies<br />

derives in part from the expanded list of topics on which UNCITRAL has focused.<br />

In a 1981 Report to the Commission, UNCITRAL's Secretariat reports success on<br />

its initial "four fields of interest: the law of international sales of goods, carriage of<br />

goods by sea, international negotiable instruments and international commercial<br />

arbitration." 69 In each of these fields, the Secretariat reported the adoption of<br />

"comprehensive texts," but went on to opine that "[t]he subject matter of the<br />

Commission's new programme of work does not always require a comprehensive<br />

solution. The difference in magnitude of the problems considered may have an<br />

impact of the final form which the Commission's work might take." 70 Specifically,<br />

the Secretariat suggested that, if it was not feasible for the Commission to propose<br />

"a text ready for adoption," then it might instead adopt a "guidelines approach" on<br />

the grounds that "the development of guidelines or recommendations may be an<br />

appropriate first objective, leaving until later a decision as to whether further actions<br />

are desirable." 7 By 1985, UNCITRAL promulgated its Recommendation on the<br />

Legal Value of Computer Records. 72<br />

Neither a convention nor a model law would seem appropriate tools when law<br />

reform looks to reject out-moded law in favor of new, more modern text. These<br />

sorts of international instruments are ill-suited to suggesting that national actors to<br />

reform existing bodies of law because, to some degree, they demand adherence to<br />

the terms of the international instrument. For example, national actors face a binary<br />

choice with regard to a convention: accede to the terms of the convention in full or<br />

fail to follow it at all. Model laws permit slightly greater freedom, in that domestic<br />

legislatures may adopt implementing legislation that fails to adopt all of the<br />

provisions of the model law, but it stretches the concept of a "model" law to invite<br />

68. Welcome to the UNCITRAL Web Site, supra note 2. A similar statement appears at the index to<br />

UNCITRAL's website. Welcome to the UNCITRAL Web Site: Highlights,<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/index.html. The "frequently asked questions" section of the website<br />

defines both "harmonization" and "unification" and provides examples of each. FAQ - Origin, Mandate<br />

and Composition of UNCITRAL, supra note 5. However, nowhere does the website define<br />

"modernization."<br />

69. The Secretary-General, Report of the Secretary-General on the Question of Co-ordination:<br />

Direction of the Work of the Commission, at 251, U.N. Doc. A/CN.9/203 (1981), available at<br />

http://daccessdds.un.org/doc/UNDOC/GEN/NL8/102/43/PDF/NL810243.pdf?OpenEement.<br />

70. Id..<br />

71. Id.; see also id. at 252 (further discussing advantages and disadvantages of conventions, model<br />

laws, and recommendations).<br />

72. We do not claim that UNCITRAL has not relied on conventions or model laws when it seeks to<br />

"modernize" global commercial laws to accord with modern commercial practices: it has. For examples of<br />

"in with the new" modernization accomplished by means of conventions and model laws, see supra note 26<br />

(referring to Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Commerce with Guide to Enactment (1996); Model <strong>Law</strong> on<br />

Electronic Signatures with Guide to Enactment (2001); and United Nations Convention on the Use of<br />

Electronic Communications in International Contracts (2005)). Our claim is that recommendations,<br />

legislative guides, and other more flexible international instruments have been instrumental in<br />

UNCITRAL's shift from the harmonization and unification to the modernization and harmonization of<br />

trade law, not that they are a necessary requisite for modernization.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 491 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

national actors to pick and choose among the provisions of a model law. Not<br />

surprisingly, then, we find that both the Insolvency and Secured Transactions<br />

Working Groups consciously chose to work on legislative guides rather than a model<br />

law or convention. 7 In its Reports to the Working Groups on Possible Future Work<br />

on Insolvency and Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong>s, intended to convince the Commission<br />

to take on the task of drafting these legislative guides, UNCITRAL's Secretariat<br />

talks openly about the need for flexibility in modernizing these areas of the law,<br />

particularly in light of the global dissensus the drafters faced. Both reports<br />

emphasize the need for a legislative guide rather than a convention or model law.<br />

When reporting to the Working Group on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, the Secretariat put<br />

the issue this way:<br />

It is not always possible to draft specific uniform provisions in a suitable<br />

form, such as a convention or a model law, for incorporation into national<br />

legal systems. One reason may be, for example, that national legal systems<br />

use widely disparate legislative techniques and approaches for solving a<br />

given issue, or that <strong>State</strong>s are not yet ready to agree on a common<br />

approach or a common rule. A further reason may be that not all <strong>State</strong>s<br />

perceive a sufficiently urgent need to find a uniform solution to a<br />

particular issue. 74<br />

In this event, "it may be appropriate not to attempt to elaborate a text in the form of<br />

a model statute, but to limit the action to a set of principles or legislative<br />

recommendations." 7 In other words, given the Working Group's need for flexibility,<br />

it may be best to produce a legislative guide rather than a model law.<br />

A similar debate on the form of reform occurred within the Secured<br />

Transactions Working Group. Before beginning to draft the Legislative Guide on<br />

Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong>, Working Group VI debated the merits of a "convention<br />

unifying substantive rules governing security interests," a "convention establishing<br />

uniform conflict rules," a "convention or model law creating an international<br />

security interest," a "statement of principles accompanied by a model law," and<br />

"more limited solutions," such as a "statement of principles accompanied by a legal<br />

guide. 7 6 The Secured Transactions Working Group favored the latter both because<br />

"at present the national legal systems are still too divergent" and because a<br />

convention or model law would not be "flexible enough to take into account the<br />

varying circumstances of the countries of the world.... " 7 7<br />

73. However, legislative guides are the invention of neither the Working Group on Insolvency nor on<br />

Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong>. UNCITRAL promulgated earlier legislative guides with its 1987 Legal Guide<br />

on Drawing up International Contracts for the Construction of Industrial Works and, later, in 2000, its<br />

Legislative Guide on Privately Financed Infrastructure Projects. In this arena, the Legislative Guide on<br />

Privately Financed Infrastructure Projects served as a stepping stone toward the adoption of Model<br />

Legislative Provisions on Privately Financed Infrastructure Projects. The preface to the Model Legislative<br />

Provisions explains the relationship between the Legislative Guide and the provisions as clear cut.<br />

UNCITRAL MODEL LEGISLATIVE PROVISIONS ON PRIVATELY FINANCED INFRASTRUCTURE PROJECTS,<br />

supra note 28, at iii. Work on the Model Legislative Provisions followed nearly on the heels of the Guide,<br />

although it was agreed to carve out several subjects from the scope of topics previously covered in the<br />

Guide for fear that consensus would not be reached on these topics in the Model Legislative Provisions.<br />

74. UNCITRAL, Possible Future Work on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 8, para. 167.<br />

75. Id. para. 168.<br />

76. UNCITRAL, Security Interests, supra note 65, paras. 46-62.<br />

77. Id., para. 46.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 492 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

B. Redefining Harmonization to Meet the Challenges of Modernization<br />

UNCITRAL reconciled its goal to promote "in with the new" and "out with the<br />

old" modernization with its core mission - the "progressive harmonization and<br />

unification" of the law of trade-by expanding the definition of harmonization to<br />

subsume modernizing law reform. Currently, UNCITRAL defines harmonization<br />

"as the process through which domestic laws may be modified to enhance<br />

predictability in cross-border commercial transactions," 78 but it did not always<br />

conceive of harmonization so expansively.<br />

UN documents pre-dating the creation of UNCITRAL define "harmonization"<br />

in a way that approximates or, at least, approaches "unification." In the year before<br />

UNCITRAL was created, the UN General Assembly requested the Secretary-<br />

General to submit to it a comprehensive report on the need for UNCITRAL. 9 This<br />

Resolution 2102 (XX) explained the UN's preliminary interest in establishing a UNconnected<br />

international organization on trade law as based on a recognition "that<br />

conflicts and divergencies arising from the laws of different <strong>State</strong>s in matters relating<br />

to international trade constitute an obstacle to the development of world trade...<br />

.,," It described the mission of such an organization as focused on the "progressive<br />

unification and harmonization""' of trade law "by promoting the adoption of<br />

international conventions, uniform laws, standard contract provisions, general<br />

conditions of sale, standard trade terms and other measures .... ,"2<br />

In response to Resolution 2102 (XX), the Secretary-General commissioned a<br />

report from Prof. Clive M. Schmitthoff of the City of London College, a prominent<br />

scholar on the law of international trade and conflicts of law, and, in September<br />

1966, Prof. Schmitthoff submitted a lengthy report to the Secretary-General. 83 Like<br />

Resolution 2102 (XX), the Schmitthoff Report referred to "the progressive<br />

harmonization and unification of the law of international trade . . . ."" It referred to<br />

"harmonization" as a technique for "reduc[ing] conflicts and divergencies arising [in]<br />

international trade [law]," 89 and described unification as "[tihe most effective<br />

78. FAQ - Origin, Mandate and Composition of UNCITRAL, supra note 5. This definition seems<br />

intended to disassociate "harmonization" from "unification." In the same "frequently asked questions"<br />

section of the UNCITRAL's website, we are told that "'[ulnification' may be seen as the adoption by<br />

<strong>State</strong>s of a common legal standard governing particular aspects of international business transactions." Id.<br />

These definitions go on to distinguish harmonization from unification in terms of the international<br />

instruments most likely to be employed to pursue each interest: "A model law or a legislative guide is an<br />

example of a text which is drafted to harmonize domestic law, while a convention is an international<br />

instrument which is adopted by <strong>State</strong>s for the unification of the law at an international level." Id.<br />

79. G.A. Res. 2102 (XX), U.N. GAOR, 20th Sess., Supp. No. 14, U.N. Doc. AJ6014 (Dec. 20, 1965),<br />

available at http://www.un.org/documents/ga/res/20/ares20.htm (follow "2102 (XX)" hyperlink).<br />

80. Id.<br />

81. Id. Note the inversion of these terms by the time Resolution 2205 (XXI) establishes UNCITRAL;<br />

this phrase shifts from "progressive unification and harmonization" to "progressive harmonization and<br />

unification." Compare G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1, with G.A. Res. 2102 (XX), supra note 79.<br />

82. G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1.<br />

83. See The Secretary-General, Report of the Secretary-General, para. 2, delivered to the General<br />

Assembly, U.N. Doc. A16396 & Add.1, Add.2 (Sept. 23, 1966), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/yearbooks/archives-e/A-6396-E.pdf.<br />

84. Id. para. 8.<br />

85. Id. paras. 15-17 (surveying existing work in the field of harmonization and unification of the law of<br />

international trade and reviewing legal techniques employed in "reduc[ing] conflicts and divergencies<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 493 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

method of conflict avoidance . . . "6 Implicit in the Schmitthoff Report is a view of<br />

harmonization as the convergence of legal rules toward a unified code of conduct; in<br />

this view, harmonization would, over the long run, approach a unification of legal<br />

rules.<br />

This substance-focused definition of harmonization also permeates UN<br />

Resolution 2205 (XXI), which subsequently established UNCITRAL. When it<br />

created UNCITRAL, the General Assembly "[r]eaffirm[ed] its conviction that<br />

divergencies arising from the laws of different <strong>State</strong>s in matters relating to<br />

international trade constitute one of the obstacles to the development of world<br />

trade. ' ' w The decision to establish a Commission was based on a belief that "the<br />

extensive development of international trade" was best advanced by removing<br />

"divergencies arising from the laws of different <strong>State</strong>s," differences which would<br />

dissipate "by promoting the adoption of international conventions, uniform laws,<br />

standard contract provisions, general conditions of sale, standard trade terms and<br />

other measures.... "8 This is a "hard" definition of harmonization that views<br />

harmonization in terms of the convergence of non-uniform national laws around an<br />

agreed upon international standard. It is at the same time, however, a definition of<br />

harmonization couched in terms of the pragmatic and progressive ends it envisions:<br />

harmonization is sought in order to enable international trade and not for its own<br />

sake; international trade is viewed as favoring "the interests of all peoples" and<br />

"particularly those of developing countries" because "international trade cooperation<br />

among <strong>State</strong>s is an important factor in the promotion of friendly relations<br />

and, consequently, in the maintenance of peace and security.....90<br />

Even this "hard" definition of harmonization leaves room for ambiguity. Did<br />

UNCITRAL view harmonization as intended to remove all dissensus among<br />

national laws, or simply to reduce the number of divergencies and their impact on<br />

international trade? Some support for a "unification over time" definition of<br />

harmonization can be found in the form of legal technologies employed by<br />

UNCITRAL: Conventions look for a single set of principles or legal rules that can<br />

garner international agreement; a model law differs from a convention more in terms<br />

of its means of implementation than in the number of options and alternatives it<br />

arising [in] international trade [law]" and finding two basic techniques: "choice of law rules" and the<br />

"harmonization and unification of substantive rules").<br />

86. Id. para. 18. The Schmitthoff Report refers to "harmonization and unification" as the<br />

",preventive' method" of private international law because it "has the purpose of avoiding law conflicts"<br />

thus preventing the need to rely on choice of law rules. Id. para. 17. It describes both harmonization and<br />

unification as achievable because "[t]he similarity of the law of international trade transcends the division<br />

of the world between countries of free enterprise and countries of centrally planned economy, and between<br />

the legal families of the civil law of Roman inspiration and the common law of English tradition." Id. para.<br />

22. The report identifies the primary obstacles to harmonization and unification, not as dissensus in the<br />

law of trade, but rather the existence of a plethora of international law reforming institutions whose work<br />

overlapped and whose membership represented developed nations, predominantly in Europe and North<br />

America, and not developing nations. Id. para. 210. The Schmitthoff Report recommended the formation<br />

of a UN-related international law reform entity on the grounds that it would provide more inclusive<br />

representation of the nation's legal and economic systems and, thus, better coordinate among other<br />

international actors. Id. para. 225. His conception of UNCITRAL, thus, was primarily as a coordinating<br />

entity that derived the representative benefits of the UN.<br />

87. G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1, pt. I.<br />

88. Id.<br />

89. Id.<br />

90. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 494 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

leaves open for national deliberation." UNCITRAL has relied predominantly on<br />

conventions and model laws when addressing national actors. We also find support<br />

for a "reduction of differences over time" perspective on harmonization, although<br />

evidence of this "softer" definition of harmonization emerges only slowly over time.<br />

UNCITRAL's first international instruments directed to national actors are<br />

conventions-namely, the Convention on the Limitations Period in the International<br />

Sales of Goods, the Convention on Carriage of Goods by Sea, and the Convention<br />

on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods, adopted in 1974, 1978, and 1980,<br />

respectively-but two years later, in 1982, UNCITRAL promulgated the Unit of<br />

Account Provision and Provisions for the Adjustment of the Limit of Liability in<br />

International Transport and Liability Conventions, model legal provisions but not a<br />

model law. Model legal provisions do not attempt to cover an area of commercial<br />

law in its entirety. Because they intentionally leave some portion of the topic for<br />

non-uniform national laws, they are best described as intended to reduce rather than<br />

eradicate divergencies among national laws; they look for harmony on only a limited<br />

set of issues. Nonetheless, model legal provisions do offer national actors a single set<br />

of options around which to converge.<br />

The next UNCITRAL product directed to a public audience, the<br />

Recommendation on the Legal Value of Computer Records, dated 1985, cannot be<br />

described as seeking either uniformity or harmonization on the topic of<br />

computerization in commercial transactions. As noted earlier, 92 the<br />

Recommendation speaks only in broad generalities and merely recommends that<br />

national actors review and update existing laws to account for technological<br />

developments. This Recommendation should not be viewed as a rejection by<br />

UNCITRAL of an interest in reaching international consensus on a single unified set<br />

of principles on the topics of computerization and electronic commerce, for the<br />

Recommendation was followed, nearly immediately, with a long string of<br />

conventions 93 and model laws. 4 We note, however, that the model law projects<br />

changed during this period. Beginning with the Model <strong>Law</strong> on Procurement of<br />

Goods and Construction, all subsequent model law projects are joined with an<br />

accompanying guide to enactment.<br />

91. But even this unifying ideal suffers from practical limitations. Neither conventions nor model laws<br />

are self-enforcing. Conventions require national actors to sign, ratify, and accede to the terms of the<br />

convention. Model laws leave even more discretion to national actors' decisions to abide by its terms;<br />

model laws are not binding on <strong>State</strong>s unless domestic legislatures adopt implementing legislation. With<br />

either technology, uniformity is achieved one nation at a time, and, thus, "universally" only over time.<br />

Moreover, UNCITRAL's practice of consensual decisionmaking limits the extent of the uniformity that<br />

either form of international instrument can achieve. To reach consensus on the terms of a convention or<br />

model law, UNCITRAL may agree not to cover some more controversial topic; these gaps in the<br />

convention or model law permit divergent national practices to persist, contrary to the need for "one<br />

unified" rule on the topic.<br />

92. See supra notes 54-55 and accompanying text.<br />

93. These are the Convention on International Bills of Exchange and International Promissory Notes<br />

(1988), Convention on the Liability of Operators of Transport Terminals in International Trade (1991),<br />

and Convention on Independent Guarantees and Stand-by Letters of Credit (1995). See supra Table 1.<br />

94. These are the Model <strong>Law</strong> on International Credit Transfers (1992), Model <strong>Law</strong> on Procurement<br />

of Goods and Construction with Guide to Enactment (1993). Model <strong>Law</strong> on Procurement of Goods,<br />

Construction and Services, with Guide to Enactment (1994), Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Commerce with<br />

Guide to Enactment (1996), and Model <strong>Law</strong> on Cross-Border Insolvency with Guide to Enactment (1997).<br />

See supra Table 1.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 495 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

We see UNCITRAL's reliance on guides to enactment as connected to its<br />

recognition of the pragmatic difficulties of promoting "the progressive<br />

harmonization and unification" of the law of trade by means of a model law. While<br />

on their face harmonizing, model laws reduce the divergencies among national laws<br />

only if national actors enact implementing legislation that replicates the terms of the<br />

model law. Guides to enactment are intended to explain the model law to a<br />

domestic legislature; they advocate enactment of implementing legislation.<br />

UNCITRAL recognized that national delegates' willingness to adopt the text of a<br />

convention or model law as an UNCITRAL product did not guarantee that their<br />

nations would accede to the terms of the convention or adopt legislation modeled on<br />

the UNCITRAL model law.<br />

If guides to enactment are used to bolster the "one rule" espoused in the model<br />

law, they would be consistent with a "unification over time" concept of<br />

harmonization, but UNCITRAL used its guides to enactment for other purposes, as<br />

well. Over time, UNCITRAL recognized that domestic legislatures could do more<br />

than enact legislation to implement a model law or reject its terms in toto. Where a<br />

Working Group could not reach consensus on some provisions in a model law, it<br />

needn't abandon the model law project in favor of a more limited set of model legal<br />

provisions that did not cover the field. For example, it could include alternative<br />

provisions in the model law (option A; option B), and leave it to domestic<br />

legislatures to choose between the two; 95 alternatively, a model law might on its face<br />

allow for domestic legislatures to adopt exclusions from its terms to reflect social or<br />

cultural norms contrary to the international norms expressed in the model law. 96 In<br />

this event, guides to enactment developed a secondary purpose: With a model law<br />

that offered an array of choices to national audiences, the accompanying guide to<br />

enactment explained how alternatives might work in practice and the competing<br />

policies and principles embedded in the choices offered.<br />

Alternative model law provisions and open-ended exclusions permitted by the<br />

terms of the model law promote a "softer," "reduction of differences over time"<br />

concept of harmonization. By 1999, UNCITRAL's Secretariat put the issue in this<br />

way:<br />

165. Within the category of model laws prepared by UNCITRAL, two<br />

texts, the Model <strong>Law</strong> on International Commercial Arbitration and the<br />

Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Commerce, illustrate the flexibility of the form.<br />

The Model <strong>Law</strong> on International Commercial Arbitration, which could be<br />

described as a procedural instrument, provides a discrete set of interdependent<br />

articles. It is recommended that, in adopting the Model <strong>Law</strong>,<br />

very few amendments or changes are required. Deviations from the<br />

Model <strong>Law</strong> text have, as a rule, very rarely been made by countries<br />

adopting enacting legislation, suggesting that it has been widely accepted<br />

as a coherent model text.<br />

166. The Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Commerce, on the other hand, is a<br />

more conceptual text. Legislation adopting or proposing to "enact" the<br />

95. See Working Group VI, supra note 32.<br />

96. See UNCITRAL MODEL LAW ON ELECrRONIC COMMERCE WITH GUIDE TO ENACTMENT, supra<br />

note 26, arts. 6-8, 11-12, 15, 17.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 496 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

Model <strong>Law</strong> largely reflects the principles of the text, but may depart from<br />

it in terms not only of drafting, but also in the combination of provisions<br />

adopted or proposed for adoption. As such, and so far as it is appropriate<br />

to distinguish between a model law and model provisions, the Model <strong>Law</strong><br />

on Electronic Commerce perhaps can be regarded as establishing a set of<br />

model principles, which are drafted in the form of legislative provisions to<br />

facilitate consideration by legislators and assist in the development of<br />

laws. 97<br />

This is a pragmatic acceptance of the limitations of second-order<br />

decisionmaking in that these "more conceptual" model laws, such as the Model <strong>Law</strong><br />

on Electronic Commerce, only indirectly and over the long haul accomplish the<br />

"harmonization" needed to promote international trade. This "conceptual" form of<br />

model law does not offer unification, even in the long run." But rather than despair<br />

of the inherent constraints of international lawmaking, UNCITRAL accepts these<br />

limits as part of the challenge.<br />

Once UNCITRAL shifts its gaze from the accepted wisdom that a convention<br />

unifies and a model law harmonizes to the notion that unification and harmonization<br />

are to be judged by looking, not at international instruments, but at domestic<br />

practices, it is only a small step to the conclusion that a legal technology, such as a<br />

legislative guide, might also harmonize domestic practices even though a legislative<br />

guide provides national actors with more than one or two options. A recognition<br />

that what matters is, not so much harmonization "on the books," but rather<br />

harmonization "in practice," might also constitute an acceptance that the form of<br />

"the book"-that is, the form of the legal technology or international instrument<br />

employed by the decisionmaking institution - is less important than its practical<br />

consequences.<br />

A changing context and a challenging diversity in the world's legal systems<br />

stimulated UNCITRAL to shift its mission and invent new forms of modernizing<br />

instruments that vindicate that mission. What, then, are the formal properties of a<br />

legislative guide that allow it to function in ways that other UNCITRAL<br />

technologies do not? What is it about a legislative guide that might stimulate<br />

modernization concomitantly with enhancing global trade across an enormous<br />

diversity of the world's legal systems? We turn to these questions in the next<br />

section.<br />

97. UNCITRAL, Possible Future Work on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 8, paras. 165-66.<br />

98. See UNCITRAL MODEL LAW ON ELECrRONIC COMMERCE WITH GUIDE TO ENACTMENT, supra<br />

note 26, at 18:<br />

9. The objectives of the Model <strong>Law</strong> are best served by the widest possible application of the<br />

Model <strong>Law</strong>. Thus, although there is provision made in the Model <strong>Law</strong> for exclusion of certain<br />

situations from the scope of articles 6, 7, 8, 11, 12, 15 and 17, an enacting <strong>State</strong> may well decide<br />

not to enact in its legislation substantial restrictions on the scope of application of the Model<br />

<strong>Law</strong>.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 497 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

II.<br />

UNCITRAL's LEGISLATIVE GUIDE ON INSOLVENCY LAW<br />

Based on a multi-faceted empirical study of UNCITRAL's Working Group on<br />

Insolvency, 9 the interplay of two broad formal strategies enabled UNCITRAL to<br />

craft a technology capable of modernizing exceedingly diverse national laws.' First,<br />

it created a combination of design elements within the structure of the Guide itself.<br />

Second, it invented a sophisticated array of rule-types that could be deployed,<br />

combined and recombined, as the consensus-building challenge demanded.<br />

A. The Design of the Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong><br />

The content and structure of the Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong><br />

exemplify the formal capacities of a technology to facilitate agreement among a<br />

broad diversity of actors and interests in a contentious policy domain. Following an<br />

introduction and glossary, the Guide is divided into two parts. Part One of the<br />

Insolvency Guide articulates broad policies and purposes common to all insolvency<br />

laws. Drawing on earlier works promulgated by the International Monetary Fund,<br />

the Asian Development Bank and the World Bank, Part One identifies nine "key<br />

objectives," providing high order principles that orient the remainder of the Guide.<br />

They are accompanied by a word of caution regarding the tensions among these<br />

fundamental purposes. Part Two of the Guide details the core provisions for an<br />

effective and efficient insolvency law. It comprises the lion's share of the Guide, and<br />

provides a detailed discussion of the core provisions of a modern insolvency law.<br />

Divided into eight sections (and twenty subparts), it covers topics ranging from<br />

commencement to the closing of a liquidation or reorganization proceeding.<br />

Cognizant of the difficulty of absorbing this amount of detail, the Guide takes great<br />

pains to organize this commentary with indices and headings and to sum up each<br />

section with Recommendations that derive from the lengthier commentary that<br />

precedes them. The Guide provides 198 numbered recommendations divided<br />

among the twenty topics it covers. Occasionally, the Guide provides commentary on<br />

a topic (institutional framework; corporate groups), but no recommendations.<br />

Three formal elements of the Guide demonstrate how the Secretariat crafted a<br />

product that could embrace existing extremes of substantive and institutional<br />

variation.<br />

1. Glossary. The Guide begins with a Glossary. What first appears as a<br />

technical aid to an understanding of the text, in fact functions as a formal mechanism<br />

for defusing national contests over legal concepts and terminology. UNCITRAL<br />

both adopts and creates a universal vocabulary to standardize usage within the<br />

Guide. By relying on no particular country's terminology, and instead creating its<br />

own internal language, the Guide adeptly promotes "out with the old"<br />

99. The empirical sources for this study include the classic social science methods of (a) participant<br />

observation (attendance at all meetings of the Working Group, the Commission, and expert groups held<br />

between formal meetings), (b) interviews of participants-staff, delegates, observers-at all stages of<br />

deliberations from the Commission's initial exploratory meeting to its final vote, and (c) statistical analysis<br />

of all speech turns by delegates at all formal meetings. The sources also include a legal analysis of the<br />

Working Group's texts, most importantly its final authorized version, and those of UNCITRAL from its<br />

founding.<br />

100. For a discussion of the degree of dissensus that separates national laws on insolvency practices,<br />

see Block-Lieb & Halliday, supra note 18.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 498 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

modernization of insolvency laws without the need for explicit rejection of terms or<br />

concepts. In addition to the obvious political advantage of avoiding identification of<br />

UNCITRAL's products with any particular legal system, this also has the juridical<br />

effect of detaching national actors, such a legislatures and judges, from standard<br />

interpretations of terms in their own legal traditions. '<br />

The Glossary accomplishes this feat of transcending the particularity of the<br />

national with several techniques. It does adopt terms that are terminological<br />

universals, such as "debtor" and "creditor." These terms are common to all legal<br />

families. In other instances, UNCITRAL embraces terms that are associated with a<br />

politically important actor. For example, in both the Guide and the Model <strong>Law</strong> on<br />

Cross-Border Insolvency, UNCITRAL solved a problem of jurisdiction over crossborder<br />

insolvencies by incorporating the term "centre of main interests," which was<br />

first employed in the European Union's draft Convention on Cross-Border<br />

Insolvency.' °2 Although its Regulation on Cross-Border Insolvency was not adopted<br />

by the EU and its member states until after promulgation of UNCITRAL's work<br />

product on the same topic, UNCITRAL successfully co-opted a term first coined by<br />

a "competing" international lawmaking body.<br />

The Guide also excludes terms that are associated with one particular<br />

insolvency system: even though concepts of U.S. bankruptcy law informed many of<br />

the debates over the Guide, the Guide does not uniformly adopt terms of art from<br />

the U.S. Bankruptcy Code or practice. For example, the Guide addresses the<br />

treatment of contracts, but refers to the continuation of such contracts rather than to<br />

their assumption as is true under U.S. law. As another example, the Guide<br />

recommends that stay or moratorium of creditor collection activity ensue upon the<br />

commencement of an insolvency proceeding, but nowhere refers to it as an<br />

"automatic stay. ' '<br />

In addition, the Guide invents terms to avoid aligning itself with one country<br />

and to provide universal umbrella concepts that transcend the practices associated<br />

with particular insolvency regimes. UNCITRAL's term "insolvency representative"<br />

corresponds with no such usage in any legal system, yet it encompasses every<br />

configuration of insolvency actor in the world's insolvency systems, including not<br />

only roles (e.g., trustees, liquidators, administrators, insolvency practitioners) but<br />

also professionals (e.g., lawyers, accountants, bureaucrats). UNCITRAL's term<br />

"court" is also a universal defined to include any kind of supervising agency,<br />

including both administrative agencies and judicial decisionmakers.<br />

At times, this invented language launders terms that might appear too<br />

derivative of one country's system. Rather than adopt the U.S. term of "adequate<br />

101. Interview by Terence Halliday with 2065A (Dec. 7, 2000) (unpublished interview, on file with<br />

authors). The interviewee stated:<br />

If you use a particular word in this actual text, the judge in one legal system will give it its own<br />

meaning, and we don't want the judge to give it that historical meaning. We want to give the<br />

international meaning, which is then spelled out. So we want not to confuse the user of the text<br />

by using a text which he learned in law school.<br />

Id.<br />

102. European Union Convention on Insolvency Proceedings, Nov. 23, 1995, 35 I.L.M. 1223.<br />

103. Later versions removed one or two terms too closely associated with one country, such as the<br />

U.S. concept of "super-priority," or the English and European concept of "retention of title."<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 499 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

protection," the Glossary adopts the concept but with another term-"protection of<br />

value." ' ° And in the text of the Guide, rather than referring to the U.S. concept of<br />

"pre-packaged" reorganization plans to describe a practice of reorganization,<br />

UNCITRAL adopts the phrase "expedited procedures," even though the underlying<br />

meaning is virtually identical. Similarly, retention of title transactions, which has<br />

created a major sticking point for UNCITRAL's Working Group on Secured<br />

Transactions <strong>Law</strong>, are referred to only obliquely. Rather than refer to the<br />

transaction, the Guide refers only to the subject of the transaction, and then talks in<br />

terms of "third party-owned assets," which are in turn defined to include, among<br />

other assets, those that are the subject of a retention-of-title transaction.<br />

UNCITRAL's manipulation of form to solve problems that are inherently<br />

political extends to terms and concepts. In the former case, it embraces a diversity of<br />

substance or practice with the substitution or invention of a term. This may be as<br />

little as substituting a label or as much as inventing a higher order term. In the latter<br />

case, it invents a new concept to solve a distinctively transnational problem, such as<br />

deciding on jurisdiction in cross-border insolvency cases.<br />

2. Commentary. The Working Group on Insolvency pitched the text of its<br />

Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> between a minimalist threshold, which would<br />

go no farther than producing a comparative report, and a maximal threshold, which<br />

would include only statutory language. Most of the twenty substantive sections in<br />

the Guide present commentary followed by recommendations.<br />

The commentary combines several elements. First, it usually identifies an issue<br />

and indicates why it is important. Second, it may offer a principle in relation to the<br />

issue and justify the principle (e.g., "it is desirable that the commencement standard<br />

be transparent and certain .... ",;105 'an insolvency law will need to clearly identify<br />

the assets" because this will produce "transparency and predictability . ,).106<br />

Third, where there is considerable cross-national variation on an issue, the<br />

commentary presents a comparative analysis, without ever identifying countries. For<br />

example, on standards for commencing an insolvency proceeding, the Guide<br />

distinguishes between a cash flow and a balance sheet test of insolvency. 7 Fourth, it<br />

discusses the benefits and deficiencies of the alternatives, focusing both on juridical<br />

and practical advantages and disadvantages. 08 Finally, it often expresses a<br />

preference (e.g., it is increasingly recognized that a certain course of action will have<br />

more advantages to the economy)." 9 Or, if two possibilities are acceptable, the<br />

Guide may explicate how the two versions might be related to each other. For<br />

example, on the test for insolvency, it explains why a cash flow test might be<br />

acceptable, and goes on to note that a balance sheet test should not be used alone<br />

°<br />

but only in combination with a cash flow test.<br />

The commentary thereby serves both internal and external functions. For<br />

purposes of reaching agreement among the Working Group, the commentary<br />

104. INSOLVENCY GUIDE, supra note 15, at 6. In this case, the definition of "protection of value"<br />

does include in parentheses the statement that "(in some jurisdictions referred to as 'adequate<br />

protection.')". Id.<br />

105. Id. pt. 2, I(B)(1), para. 21.<br />

106. Id. pt. 2, II(A)(1), para. 3.<br />

107. Id. pt. 2, I(B)(2)(a), (b), paras. 23-26.<br />

108. INSOLVENCY GUIDE, supra note 15, pt. 2, I(B)(2)(a), (b), paras. 23-26.<br />

109. Id.<br />

110. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 500 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

provides a space where disagreements can be defused by signaling that dissent has<br />

been heard and that points of view have been fairly aired for debate. By including<br />

contending views in the commentary, even if one of those views will be preferred<br />

over others, groups may be pacified and country delegates can signal to their<br />

ministries that their opinions were expressed and recorded. As a result, "out with<br />

the old" modernization can implicitly reject out-moded approaches by failing to<br />

include them within the recommendations offered by the Guide, but cushion this<br />

rejection in the recommendations with explanatory text in the commentary that may<br />

describe in great detail the pros and cons of the rejected approach. For purposes of<br />

implementation, the commentary has a significant didactic role for it expresses a<br />

global consensus on what issues must be addressed in legislation, it explains to<br />

national law-makers the costs and benefits of alternatives, and it offers a guide to<br />

judges, providing reasoning to support recommendations.<br />

Within the commentary, UNCITRAL engages in a rhetoric of self-validation.<br />

UNCITRAL must rely on persuasion and the intrinsic merits of a product in order to<br />

facilitate adoption by national law-makers. The Guide makes claims about the value<br />

of adopting it for investment, economic development, and integration into the world<br />

economy. On specific provisions, the Guide uses three additional techniques of<br />

persuasion of the rightness of a particular preference in the Guide and of extrinsic<br />

reasons for its adoption.<br />

First, the Guide endeavors where possible to signal that a recommendation<br />

reflects universal consensus or at least a heavy preponderance of practice. It is said,<br />

for instance, that exceptions for banking and insurance companies from coverage by<br />

insolvency laws are "widely reflected in insolvency laws" ' ' or that insolvency laws<br />

"generally permit" an application for liquidation to be made by debtors, creditors,<br />

and government agencies."'<br />

Second, if universality cannot be claimed, the Guide relies on a quantitative<br />

criterion. The commentary states that "many insolvency laws identify the minimum<br />

threshold of support required from creditors,"'. 3 or that a standard is "used<br />

extensively,"" 4 or that the "most common approach" to application of the stay is that<br />

it begins at commencement of proceedings."'<br />

Third, the Guide occasionally invokes the notion of a trend. On the highly<br />

contentious issue of whether secured property should be included in a bankruptcy<br />

estate, the world divides probably with a preponderance of countries in favor of its<br />

exclusion. Yet the move towards reorganization requires that secured property be<br />

brought the bankruptcy estate, even if a minority of countries follows that principle.<br />

Although the Guide takes the minority view, it concludes that this view is<br />

"increasingly recognized" and that inclusion has economic advantages over<br />

exclusion.<br />

The juxtaposition of the discursive commentary with the statutory-like language<br />

of the recommendations gives the Guide added flexibility. Depending on the<br />

111. INSOLVENCY GUIDE, supra note 15, pt. 2, I(A)(1)(c), para. 11, at 41.<br />

112. Id. pt. 2, I(B)(3)(a), para. 32, at 49.<br />

113. Id. pt. 2, IV(A)(5)(g), para. 47.<br />

114. Id. pt. 2, l(B)(2)(a), para. 23, at 45 (referring to the liquidity or cash flow test as "used<br />

extensively").<br />

115. Id. pt. 2, II(B)(5)(c), para. 46, at 90.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 501 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

shifting sense of the Working Group, materials on which consensus could not be<br />

reached might be shifted from the recommendations back to the commentary;<br />

conversely, materials thought to be critical by influential delegations could be made<br />

more imperative by moving them from the commentary into the form of a<br />

recommendation. The content moves to the formal locus where the micro-politics of<br />

Working Group negotiation permit.<br />

3. Recommendations. At the end of each substantive section of commentary,<br />

the Guide includes recommendations. Recommendations are always prefaced by a<br />

set of purposes, which themselves have been negotiated by delegates. 1 1 6 These<br />

statements of purposes range from a single sentence to four to six specific goals,<br />

providing both an introduction to the recommendations they precede and a<br />

statement of their intended reach.<br />

The commentary, purposes and recommendations work together to guide<br />

domestic legislatures to adopt modern insolvency laws. The commentary provides a<br />

detailed examination of each of the topics on which the Guide expresses<br />

recommendations. The key objectives and purpose provisions offer national lawmakers<br />

a checklist of issues and goals to guide law-making.<br />

We now turn to examine in detail the recommendations. The variety of forms<br />

in the recommendations provides the Guide with a repertoire of rule-types that<br />

alone or in combination enable the Guide to adjust for the degree of diversity and<br />

dissent on issues.<br />

B. Arrays of Rule-Types<br />

In the Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, the UNCITRAL Secretariat<br />

created a variety of rule-types that can be arrayed along a spectrum of specificity<br />

that ranges from broad statements of commercial norms to explicitly detailed<br />

language ready for enactment:<br />

1. Imperative recommendations propose that national legislatures take specific<br />

types of action whose content is expressly stated. These subsume several subcategories<br />

of norms.<br />

a. Substantive recommendations take the general form: "There should be a rule<br />

[about the substantive entitlements of participants in an insolvency proceeding] that<br />

[contains particular substantive provisions]." For instance, on the all-important<br />

scope of an insolvency law, a key substantive recommendation reads: "The<br />

insolvency law should govern insolvency proceedings against all debtors that engage<br />

in economic activities, whether natural or legal persons, including state-owned<br />

enterprises, and whether or not those economic activities are conducted for profit... 7<br />

b. Procedural recommendations take a similar form: "There should be a rule<br />

[about how an insolvency proceeding should be conducted] that [contains particular<br />

procedural elements]." For example, on commencement of an insolvency<br />

proceeding, a procedural recommendation provides that: "The law generally should<br />

116. Id. at 233 (stating that the "purpose of provisions relating to the reorganization plan" is "(a) To<br />

facilitate the rescue of businesses subject to the insolvency law, thereby preserving employment and, in<br />

appropriate cases, protecting investment .... ").<br />

117. INSOLVENCY GUIDE, supra note 15, Recommendation 8, at 44.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 502 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

specify that, where a creditor makes the application for commencement: (a) Notice<br />

of the application promptly is given to the debtor .... "'<br />

c. Conditional recommendations. Some imperative recommendations are<br />

conditional and provide roughly as follows: "If a rule [about some substantive or<br />

procedural topic of insolvency law] is enacted, then it should [have the following<br />

content]." For example, in the provisions on the confirmation of a reorganization<br />

plan, the Guide recognized that not all laws require that all classes must approve a<br />

plan. Even so, it directed that in this subset of nations:<br />

Where the insolvency law does not require a plan to be approved by all<br />

classes, the insolvency law should address the treatment of those classes<br />

which do not vote to approve a plan that is otherwise approved by the<br />

requisite classes. That treatment should be consistent with the grounds set<br />

forth in recommendation 152.19<br />

A conditional recommendation can be distinguished from a substantive or<br />

procedural recommendation in that, while conditional recommendations identify the<br />

content of language that might be adopted by a domestic legislature, they leave the<br />

question of whether such a rule should be enacted to local discretion. This has the<br />

tactical effect that a conditional recommendation can be combined with any number<br />

of other rules. Substantive and procedural rules might both be qualified by the<br />

condition, "if you have a substantive/procedural rule, then it should include this<br />

content." Conditional recommendations give UNCITRAL the capacity to<br />

acknowledge local contingencies and variations in an orderly way.<br />

Imperative recommendations have in common that they all provide domestic<br />

legislatures with proposed statutory language. If a legislative guide were comprised<br />

of only imperative recommendations, it would closely resemble a model law.<br />

2. Constraining recommendations are not explicitly directive of particular<br />

legislative language, although they are conducive to convergence. Often they point<br />

in a direction and then give choices. We discern at least three variants of these.<br />

a. Baseline recommendations take the form - "there should be a rule on a topic,<br />

and it should include at least the following elements (with the implication that other<br />

elements might also be included)." For instance, in the section on expedited<br />

proceedings, baseline recommendations set a floor or minimal standard for<br />

commencement of such a proceeding:<br />

The insolvency law should specify that the following additional materials<br />

should accompany an application for commencement of expedited<br />

reorganization proceedings:<br />

(a) The reorganization plan and disclosure statement;<br />

(b) A description of the voluntary restructuring negotiations that preceded<br />

the making of the application for commencement, including the<br />

118. Id. Recommendation 19, at 65.<br />

119. Id. Recommendation 151, at 236.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 503 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

information provided to affected creditors to enable them to make an<br />

informed decision about the plan;<br />

(c) Certification that unaffected creditors are being paid in the ordinary<br />

course of business and that the plan does not modify or affect the rights or<br />

claims of unaffected creditors without their agreement;<br />

(d) A report of the votes of affected classes of creditors demonstrating<br />

that those classes have accepted the plan by the majorities specified in the<br />

insolvency law;<br />

(e) A financial analysis or other evidence that demonstrates that the plan<br />

satisfies all applicable requirements for reorganization; and<br />

(f) A list of the members of any creditor committee formed during the<br />

course of the voluntary restructuring negotiations.""<br />

This non-exclusive list-like many found in the Guide-merely sets minimum<br />

standards to be found in enacting legislation.<br />

b. Permissive recommendations take the form - "a country may adopt a rule<br />

that includes [X], [Y] and [Z]." Permissive recommendations are often supported by<br />

explanatory footnoted materials and commentary. They enable UNCITRAL to<br />

acknowledge the acceptability of a strongly-held preference by a nation-state,<br />

permitting it to give some guidance without endorsing the position for all nations.<br />

For example, on the protection of debtors and creditors when a stay is placed on<br />

creditors' efforts to collect on claims, the Guide grants courts power in those<br />

countries that so choose and indicates what those powers might be:<br />

The insolvency law may provide the court with the power to:<br />

(a) Require the applicant for provisional measures to provide<br />

indemnification and, where appropriate, to pay costs or fees; or<br />

(b) Impose sanctions in connection with an application for provisional<br />

121<br />

measures.<br />

The Guide often combines permissive recommendations with others, such as a<br />

substantive rule that has an imperative element plus a permissive element.<br />

c. Norms of minimalism instead take the form-"if there is to be a rule on a<br />

topic, or an exception to the rule on a topic, it should be kept to a minimum." There<br />

are many examples in the Guide of the norm of minimalism. When discussing the<br />

120. Id. Recommendation 162, at 245.<br />

121. Id. Recommendation 40, at 100.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 504 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

choice of law rules that should govern an insolvency proceeding, Recommendation<br />

31 establishes the general rule, when it provides that:<br />

The insolvency law of the <strong>State</strong> in which insolvency proceedings are<br />

commenced (lex fori concursus) should apply to all aspects of the<br />

commencement, conduct, administration and conclusion of those<br />

insolvency proceedings and their effects. 2<br />

Recommendations 32 and 33 provide two exceptions to the general rule: one<br />

pertaining to the rights and obligations of the participants in a payment or settlement<br />

system or in a regulated financial market (imperative recommendation) and another<br />

pertaining to the rejection, continuation and modification of labor contracts<br />

(permissive recommendation). On the topic of additional exceptions to the general<br />

rule in Recommendation 31, the Guide also turns to the norm of minimalism: "Any<br />

exceptions additional to recommendation 32 and 33 should be limited in number and<br />

be clearly set forth or noted in the insolvency law."<br />

The same norm of minimalism dictates the contours of Recommendation 188,<br />

on the topic of secured claims:<br />

The insolvency law should specify that a secured claim should be satisfied<br />

from the encumbered asset in liquidation or pursuant to a reorganization<br />

plan, subject to claims that are superior in priority to the secured claim, if<br />

any. Claims superior in priority to secured claims should be minimized<br />

and clearly set forth in the insolvency law. 23<br />

Recommendations applying the norm of minimalism frequently also rely on the<br />

norm of disclosure or some other specifying recommendation, as noted below.<br />

3. Focusing recommendations look only to sharpen the focus of any law<br />

adopted by a domestic legislature. We identify two of these.<br />

a. Architectural recommendations state that-"there should be rule on [some<br />

specific topic of insolvency law]," but do not specify what the rule should be. On the<br />

topic of plans of reorganization, Recommendation 185 speaks of the need to create<br />

classes of creditors and to make clear what priority they should be accorded, but it<br />

does not indicate how it should be done: "The insolvency law should specify the<br />

classes of creditors that will be affected by the commencement of insolvency<br />

proceedings and the treatment of those classes in terms of priority and<br />

distribution. 1 24<br />

The Working Group viewed it as important for an insolvency law to provide for<br />

the appointment of a committee, but did not feel the need to provide detailed<br />

directions on how that appointment should be accomplished in an insolvency law. If<br />

the architectural recommendation is very detailed about the subject of the rule on<br />

which it views the need for legislation, then it may differ only subtly from an<br />

imperative recommendation. If, on the other hand the architectural<br />

122. Id. Recommendation 31, at 73.<br />

123. Id. Recommendation 188, at 275.<br />

124. Id. Recommendation 185, at 275.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 505 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

recommendation speaks in broad generalities, it more closely resembles a norm of<br />

disclosure.<br />

b. Norms of disclosure indicate only that some rule "should be clearly and<br />

expressly set forth in the insolvency law." For example, in Recommendation 186 on<br />

priority claims in distributions, a norm of minimalism is immediately followed by a<br />

norm of disclosure in Recommendation 187. Together they read as follows:<br />

The insolvency law should establish the order in which claims are to be<br />

satisfied from the estate. 25<br />

The insolvency law should minimize the priorities accorded to unsecured<br />

claims. The law should set out clearly the classes of claims, if any, that will<br />

be entitled to be satisfied in priority in insolvency proceedings.' 26<br />

The norm of disclosure often works hand in hand with the norm of minimalism.<br />

4. Policy recommendations identify and affirm broad normative statements of<br />

insolvency law. These are the highest order principles in the Guide. They are found<br />

primarily in a list of eight governing norms or key objectives. These include the need<br />

to provide certainty in the marketplace sufficient to permit economic stability and<br />

growth, the desirability of maximizing asset values and striking a balance between<br />

liquidation and reorganization, and the need to provide timely, efficient and<br />

impartial resolution of an insolvency proceeding and to establish a framework for<br />

resolution of cross-border insolvency proceedings.<br />

Although these norms might, at first glance, be dismissed as little more than<br />

blandishments of "motherhood and apple pie," in fact, they are much more than<br />

that. Each addresses potentially ubiquitous problems in the functioning of<br />

bankruptcy systems.<br />

C. Rule- Types and Prospects for Consensual Decisionmaking<br />

A simple tally of all rule-types used in the Insolvency Legislative Guide yields<br />

ninety-one substantive recommendations, twenty procedural recommendations,<br />

twenty-two conditional recommendations, forty baseline recommendations, thirtynine<br />

permissive recommendations, fifty-eight architectural recommendations,<br />

twenty-six norms of disclosure, seven norms of minimalism and seven policy<br />

norms. 12 7 By this count, the overwhelming majority of the recommendations made in<br />

the Insolvency Guide are, thus, imperative recommendations. We found this count<br />

surprising, given that the Working Group consciously chose to frame this as a<br />

Legislative Guide rather than a model law or convention. Except in how they are<br />

framed, there is little difference between model law provisions and imperative<br />

125. Id. Recommendation 186, at 275.<br />

126. Id. Recommendation 187, at 275.<br />

127. The arithmetically astute reader will have noted that this tally exceeds the 198 numbered<br />

recommendations specified in the Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>. We exceed 198 because some of<br />

the numbered recommendations contain more than one sentence; we count each sentence in the<br />

recommendations as constituting a separate recommendation. By this count, there are 310 distinct<br />

recommendations in the Guide. For a matrix identifying and characterizing each of the recommendations<br />

contained in the Guide, see [website created by Prof. Block-Lieb].<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 506 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

recommendations. From this perspective, the Insolvency Guide appears a largely<br />

harmonizing instrument.<br />

We do not minimize the commercial importance of constraining and focusing<br />

recommendations, however. Both are critical to the goal of modernization. They<br />

each step more lightly than imperative recommendations on national sovereignty,<br />

and should in this way serve UNCITRAL's interest in not being seen to infringe<br />

unnecessarily on controversial issues of insolvency law. Moreover, even broadly<br />

stated norms serve important commercial purposes in the Guide. Delegates at the<br />

Working Group were often heard to extol the commercial benefits of transparency<br />

and predictability in an insolvency law. Norms of disclosure directly accomplish this<br />

more limited goal when delegates could not, for one reason or another, agree on the<br />

substance that an insolvency law should be recommended to follow. Not<br />

surprisingly, we observe that norms of disclosure are most likely to be employed<br />

where the subject involves insolvency law issues that infringe on subjects of social,<br />

cultural or political significance.<br />

The array of linguistic forms in which recommendations can be expressed<br />

thereby gives UNCITRAL the flexibility in a legislative guide to adjust its level of<br />

prescription to the level of consensus among the most influential blocs of delegates.<br />

This flexibility provides UNCITRAL the room to raise and lower levels of<br />

prescriptive force between and within clusters of recommendations on substantive<br />

topics. Through the flexibility obtained by this range of technologies and rule-types,<br />

UNCITRAL avoids either extreme of enunciating norms that are effectively<br />

meaningless or are so precise as to engender a backlash through encroachment on<br />

sovereignty. It permits UNCITRAL to achieve as much harmonization as necessary<br />

to the task of modernizing the insolvency laws of national actors. The Legislative<br />

Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, thus, wavers between a "unification over time" vision of<br />

harmonization and one that merely attempts a "reduction of differences over time."<br />

III. RULE-TYPES, MODERNIZATION AND HARMONIZATION<br />

The flexibility needed to modernize an area of the law-and to accomplish law<br />

reform (especially law reform on a global level) in the face of divergencies in the<br />

law-comes at a price: Flexibility may reduce the unifying influence of the law<br />

reform effort. In this section, we explain how a legislative guide containing both<br />

commentary and a range of recommendations afforded UNCITRAL the ability to<br />

both modernize and harmonize insolvency law.<br />

A. Modernization<br />

How did its use of a legislative guide permit UNCITRAL to "modernize"<br />

insolvency law, despite its need for consensual decisionmaking, despite enormous<br />

divergences among national laws on the topic of insolvency, and despite the<br />

propensity for insolvency laws to butt up against important social and political issues<br />

of national interest? In a companion piece, we argue that this range of rule types,<br />

nested in a wider formal script, provided UNCITRAL with needed flexibility to<br />

accomplish "out with the old" (and in some cases "in with the new") modernization<br />

in an area of commercial law on which there existed few global norms and great<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 507 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

disagreements cross-nationally over the policy implications of bankruptcy law. 20 The<br />

Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> achieved this feat of diplomacy in two steps,<br />

with both moves highly dependent on the formal structure of the Guide.<br />

First, the Guide builds on an international consensus on the desirability of<br />

enabling the reorganization of a viable commercial entity. 129 The eight policy<br />

norms-those key objectives based on earlier work done by the IMF and World<br />

Bank and found in Part One of the Legislative Guide-were instrumental in<br />

identifying reorganization as a central component in any "modern" insolvency<br />

statute and in providing policy-oriented touchstones to which the Guide could<br />

return, time and again, to justify both the tenor and content of reorganizationfriendly<br />

recommendations. Where an issue might affect the success of a<br />

reorganization proceeding, we find that the Guide is more likely to deviate from<br />

global norms and more likely to do so using an imperative recommendation. Thus,<br />

recommendations were crafted with an eye on whether they were central to<br />

promoting the reorganization of viable commercial entities. Where necessary to<br />

advance reorganization, the Working Group was more likely to reach for imperative<br />

recommendations. For example, despite global dissensus on the topics, the Guide<br />

contains imperative recommendations on: the breadth of property in an insolvency<br />

estate (including property subject to a security interest);' 30 the scope of any stay upon<br />

commencement (including secured creditors' collection efforts);' the use of<br />

collateral during an insolvency proceeding; 3 2 the need for and contours of postcommencement<br />

finance of an insolvency estate; " ' the standards for confirmation of a<br />

plan of reorganization' 34 and for expedited reorganization proceedings.'<br />

In other places, the Guide steps back from adopting imperative<br />

recommendations in areas that might be viewed as important to a debtor-friendly<br />

reorganization proceeding. The Guide contains several permissive<br />

recommendations on topics central to U.S.-style reorganization. For example, it<br />

provides that an insolvency law "may" provide for a debtor-in-possession<br />

reorganization proceeding in which the debtor's management is not removed from<br />

its management of day-to-day operations and is entrusted with obligations ordinarily<br />

vested in an insolvency representative, such as the obligations to negotiate a plan of<br />

reorganization.36 The Guide similarly "permits" ' but does not require the creation<br />

of a creditors' committee, stating only that an insolvency law "should facilitate the<br />

active participation of creditors in insolvency proceedings such as through a creditor<br />

committee, a special representative<br />

'<br />

or other mechanism for representation.<br />

Second, the range of available rule-types permitted the Working Group to<br />

avoid issues on which consensus was unlikely and which were likely to stall or<br />

128. Block-Lieb & Halliday, supra note 18.<br />

129. See id.<br />

130. See INSOLVENCY GUIDE, supra note 15, Recommendation 35, at 82.<br />

131. Id. Recommendations 39(a), at 99-100, & 46(b)-(c), at 102.<br />

132. Id. Recommendation 52, at 111.<br />

133. Id. Recommendations 63-68, at 118-19.<br />

134. Id. Recommendations 139-159, at 234-38.<br />

135. Id. Recommendations 160-164, at 244-46.<br />

136. Id. Recommendation 112(a), at 173.<br />

137. Id. Recommendation 130, at 204.<br />

138. Id. Recommendation 129, at 203.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 508 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

impede production of the Legislative Guide. 3 ' We find that the Working Group<br />

used softer, less constraining rule-types to minimize the likelihood that dissenting<br />

nations might abandon the central tendency of the Guide, particularly where cultural<br />

and social issues were at stake. In general, where issues of social, political or cultural<br />

significance overlapped with insolvency law, such as with questions of the priority to<br />

be accorded to workers' claims or the desirability of various exceptions to a stay or<br />

to the avoiding powers, the Guide spoke softly by employing norms of minimalism<br />

and norms of disclosure rather than imperative recommendations. 4 The Guide also<br />

avoided a hot-button that had divided the deliberations of the Working Group on<br />

Secured Transactions on its Legislative Guide-the characterization of retention-oftitle<br />

transactions in insolvency proceedings-by deferring to the secured transactions<br />

or other non-insolvency law of the enacting <strong>State</strong> rather than articulating an<br />

insolvency law solution to the issue. 4 The Guide declined to decide whether a<br />

debtor's management should be liable for trading while insolvent, or the proper<br />

treatment of corporate groups in insolvency proceedings, by discussing these issues<br />

in commentary but not reaching any recommendation on the topic.' In each case,<br />

the Guide employs an approach that is a more nuanced one than could have been<br />

accomplished in a model law, where sidestepping an issue involves avoiding any<br />

discussion of it in the legal technology. The flexible range of rule-type available in<br />

the Legislative Guide permitted UNCITRAL to emphasize the important<br />

insolvency-law issues on these hot-button topics (i.e., minimize statutory priorities<br />

for otherwise unsecured creditors; keep socially constructed exceptions to a stay or<br />

to the avoiding powers to a minimum and disclose them in the insolvency law itself;<br />

refer to non-insolvency law to differentiate between a transactions as a retention-oftitle<br />

transaction or a financing transaction), rather than remaining completely silent<br />

on the topic.<br />

The flexibility inherent in the Guide-in its commentary and its range of rule<br />

types-permitted UNCITRAL to promulgate a Legislative Guide on Insolvency<br />

<strong>Law</strong> that accomplished "out with the old" modernization of an area of law on which<br />

there was disagreement, not only on the technical details of the law, but also on its<br />

social underpinnings. However, this accomplishment might have been subversive if<br />

flexibility undermined the "unification over time" effect of the Guide. Did<br />

modernization subvert harmonization?<br />

B. Harmonization<br />

On the face of it, the Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> is only halfheartedly<br />

harmonizing. After all, only 133 of its 310 recommendations are drafted as<br />

imperative recommendations. Thus, even if we were to assume (unrealistically) that<br />

all domestic legislatures would agree to implement all of the imperative<br />

recommendations in the Insolvency Guide, the Guide would harmonize with only<br />

slightly more than half of the recommendations.' 43 If national actors similarly were<br />

139. See Block-Lieb & Halliday, supra note 18.<br />

140. Id. (listing these hot buttons).<br />

141. Id.<br />

142. Id.<br />

143. By their nature, imperative recommendations have the greatest potential for achieving<br />

harmonization: If, on a global basis, domestic legislatures were to adopt each of the these imperative<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 509 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

assumed to follow the constraining"' and focusing 5 recommendations and policy<br />

norms in the Guide, 4 6 we would not expect to see much reduction in the<br />

"divergencies arising from the laws of different <strong>State</strong>s,' 47 at least not for some time.<br />

But it would be a mistake not to view the Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> as a<br />

harmonizing technology. While a guide is not as homogenizing as a convention, or<br />

even as a model law, it nevertheless presses countries towards global statutory norms<br />

where they will find differing levels of global consensus.<br />

First, nearly half of the Guide's recommendations (133 of 310) are framed as<br />

imperative recommendations. And another forty baseline and thirty-nine permissive<br />

recommendations offer domestic legislatures concrete and detailed<br />

recommendations on the substance of an insolvency law. That a range in rule-types<br />

was employed does not, on its own, create tension with the goal of harmonization<br />

since many, if not most, of the recommendations in the Insolvency Guide provide<br />

detailed substantive rules for a domestic legislature to adopt.<br />

Moreover, where UNCITRAL viewed an issue as important, it employed<br />

imperative recommendations to express the tenor and nature of its support. This is<br />

especially true with recommendations touching on the desirability of reorganization<br />

recommendations as a part of their insolvency laws, the world's insolvency laws would harmonize on the<br />

legislative topics covered by the imperative recommendations.<br />

144. By definition, constraining recommendations identify a limited range of permissible variation<br />

among domestic insolvency laws; as a result, we would expect that convergence, a form of harmonization,<br />

would result if domestic legislatures were to follow the recommendation. But the strength of this<br />

conclusion varies depending on the nature of the constraining recommendation at issue. Baseline<br />

recommendations unequivocally lead to greater convergence, regardless of the level of dissensus among<br />

national law. Where the baseline recommendation excludes a standard approach in existence around the<br />

globe, the convergence effect is likely to be substantial. Norms of minimalism, which contain only broad<br />

statements that exceptions should be kept to a minimum, might also slowly lead to convergence. As<br />

legislatures "keep exceptions to a minimum," they may converge around a global consensus regarding the<br />

bare minimum, essential exceptions. But a norm of minimalism does not, on its face, require this result.<br />

Permissive recommendations are even less likely to result in harmonization. Permissive<br />

recommendations may not lead to greater convergence, because, unlike baseline recommendations that<br />

identify a limited range of acceptable possibilities, permissive recommendations open up rather than<br />

constrain substantive choices. This is especially true if the permissive recommendation indicates that an<br />

insolvency law "may" provide for a rule that is inconsistent with global norms. Where the<br />

recommendation "permits" results that fly in the face of global consensus, the Guide may have modernized<br />

insolvency law but has, at the same time, produced less uniformity in the law. In some instances,<br />

permissive recommendations state that an insolvency law "may" adopt a rule that the commentary<br />

identifies as out of step with the global consensus (and generally does so in order to promote the goal of<br />

promoting reorganization); in others, the permissive recommendation reflects the Working Groups'<br />

reluctance to "choose" among approaches. In the first case, the permissive recommendation is deharmonizing;<br />

in the second, the permissive recommendation simply permits a disharmonious status quo to<br />

persist. If a permissive recommendation identifies an otherwise controversial legislative position as one<br />

among several possible approaches that UNCITRAL approves, the Guide moves away from convergence<br />

around the status quo; it may, at the same time, however, serve as a hard push toward convergence at a<br />

new global equilibrium-stirring the pot may eventually push the global standard toward a newly<br />

convergent position over time, but only in the long run.<br />

145. The harmonizing influence of architectural recommendations in the Guide is unclear, since they<br />

provide no substantive direction to domestic legislatures. Similarly, norms of disclosure will have not<br />

converging influence, on their own, unless we also assume that simply by requiring a legislature to place its<br />

insolvency laws "on the books" it will discourage non-convergent rules from being adopted.<br />

146. Like focusing recommendations, the harmonizing influence of policy norms is unclear since they,<br />

too, offer little in the way of content.<br />

147. G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 510 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

or viewed as essential to a reorganization-friendly insolvency regime."' In addition,<br />

there are more than several conditional and permissive recommendations important<br />

(but not central) to an insolvency law intended to facilitate reorganization<br />

proceedings, such as a recommendation providing that an insolvency law "may"<br />

provide for a debtor-in-possession regime and "may" institute a system in which a<br />

"committee of creditors" provides a check on the powers of a debtor in possession.' 49<br />

These permissive recommendations may not "require" a domestic legislature to<br />

adopt implementing statutory language, but where a legislature is so inclined the<br />

Guide provides detailed guidance on how to achieve such a result.<br />

The Legislative Guide, thus, simultaneously accomplishes different levels of<br />

harmonization. The 133 imperative recommendations provide "unification over<br />

time" with the specificity and range that closely resemble model legal provisions<br />

coupled with a guide to enactment. The remaining recommendations - those that<br />

constrain, focus and set policy norms - may not lead to a single international<br />

standard, even when considered in light of long stretches of time, because they sit<br />

comfortably within a range of national variation. Nonetheless, these more flexible<br />

recommendations nearly all "reduce differences over time," and so "harmonize"<br />

consistent with the goal of modernization. Even the recommendations that are<br />

devoid of content, such as the architectural recommendations, and the norms of<br />

minimalism and disclosure, "harmonize" in the broadest sense of the term "as the<br />

process through which domestic laws may be modified to enhance predictability in<br />

cross-border commercial transactions. '' "0<br />

The Guide makes a persuasive case for the modernization of insolvency law,<br />

but only time will tell which recommendations nations will implement and, thus,<br />

whether it will have a harmonizing effect. Regardless of whether the Guide should<br />

be viewed as an instrument of "unification over time" or "reduction of differences<br />

over time"-and it is both-the harmonizing effect of the Legislative Guide on<br />

Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> will only be felt "over time." To assess the harmonizing effect of the<br />

Guide, we will need to wait to judge the influence of the Guide "on the ground;" we<br />

will need to study the legislation it inspires and the implementation of that<br />

legislation by courts, insolvency representatives and insolvency professionals.<br />

IV. MODERNIZATION AND GLOBAL LAW REFORM<br />

We have argued that over the forty years since its inception, UNCITRAL both<br />

broadened and shifted its mission. While created to promote the "progressive<br />

harmonization and unification" of the law of trade, it now also views itself as an<br />

agent for the "modernization and harmonization" of trade law. The goals are not<br />

disconnected. Both follow from an interest in promoting an expansion of<br />

international trade, particularly trade with developing and under-developed nations.<br />

At its inception, UNCITRAL was conceived around the notion that "divergencies<br />

arising from the laws of different <strong>State</strong>s in matters relating to international trade<br />

constitute one of the obstacles to the development of world trade."'.'. It now<br />

148. See supra notes 117-119 and accompanying text.<br />

149. See supra note 121 and accompanying text.<br />

150. FAQ - Origin, Mandate and Composition of UNCITRAL, supra note 5.<br />

151. G.A. Res. 2205 (XXI), supra note 1.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 511 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

understands that these "divergencies" constitute only one "obstacle to the<br />

development of world trade," and perhaps a relatively unimportant obstacle at that.<br />

By embracing "modernization," UNCITRAL looks to tackle obstacles that go<br />

beyond divergencies among national laws. It has taken on the charge of law reform<br />

writ large.<br />

In order to execute its expanded shift in mission, UNCITRAL found it<br />

necessary to invent new legal technologies. Table 1 demonstrates that UNCITRAL<br />

has employed, not only conventions, model laws and model legal provisions, but also<br />

recommendations, guides to enactment, legal guides and legislative guides. We have<br />

shown that the Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> is a skillfully crafted set of<br />

norms that enabled UNCITRAL concomitantly to push towards an overarching<br />

global norm-the value of corporate reorganization as a complement to corporate<br />

liquidation-while allowing significant flexibility for national lawmakers to<br />

modernize their own laws in ways appropriately adapted to variations in legal<br />

families, economic circumstances, and policy preferences, among others. As a result,<br />

this explicitly modernizing Legislative Guide also aspires to some measure of<br />

harmonization, thus, enabling UNCITRAL to lean towards the current primacy it<br />

accords modernization without losing touch with its original mandate.<br />

Nevertheless, one or two puzzles remain that warrant further comment. For<br />

the most part, we have explained UNCITRAL's shift in mission as an adaptation to<br />

changes in the world of commerce. However, another story might be told that is<br />

consistent with the experience of many organizations. UNCITRAL is nested within<br />

at least three organizational contexts. It is a very small entity within the United<br />

Nations system. To justify its own existence, to expand its budget, and to enable the<br />

UN itself to demonstrate its responsiveness in a changing world, UNCITRAL may<br />

have been compelled to show its relevance to a world where transitions from<br />

command to market economies required new law, or where financial crises required<br />

legal institution-building, or where the legal infrastructure of markets goes far<br />

beyond the substantive domains of its founding. If this could not be managed within<br />

the constraints of its founding mandate, then its senior management was pressed to<br />

reinvent its mission and technologies. To the extent that UNCITRAL could show<br />

itself responsive to demands upon the United Nations that it be more proactive in<br />

the legal construction of markets, then UNCITRAL would ensure its viability and<br />

perhaps even expansion within the UN.<br />

UNCITRAL also exists in a field of organizations concerned with law reform.<br />

Since the Asian financial crises, a variety of international organizationsinternational<br />

financial institutions such as the World Bank and IMF, regional<br />

development banks such as the Asian Development Bank, clubs of nations such as<br />

the G-7, G-22 and OECD-together with expert professional associations (in the<br />

insolvency field these prominently include INSOL, IBA, and ABA) all moved into<br />

fields of law reform thought to be salient to developing countries and transitional<br />

economies. Insolvency and secured transactions featured prominently among these.<br />

In the insolvency field, for a short period it seemed as if UNCITRAL would be<br />

marginalized by initiatives of the World Bank, IMF and Asian Development Bank.<br />

But perception was short lived. UNCITRAL's flexible technology, coupled with its<br />

legitimate deliberative process, gave it an edge that no other organization could<br />

match. "Modernization" provided the substantive reach to treat national bankruptcy<br />

law. Reliance on a legislative guide format gave it the flexibility to be salient to the<br />

entire world, while also integrating constructively -perhaps even transcending-the<br />

previous efforts of potential rivals. The flexibility of a legislative guide enabled<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 512 2006-2007


2007<br />

HARMONIZATION AND MODERNIZATION<br />

UNCITRAL to be competitive with other international organizations and ultimately<br />

to emerge with a global standard to which its potential rivals acceded.<br />

By the same logic, the matching of a flexible technology to an expansive goal<br />

permitted UNCITRAL's leadership to take onto its agenda issues at the heart of the<br />

ideological consensus about law and markets. Both the Washington Consensus and<br />

post-Washington Consensus champion the regulatory import of law for the<br />

liberalization of national markets as well as the integration of global markets. Once<br />

bankruptcy law became part of the agreed-upon bundle of a "modern" regulatory<br />

apparatus, then UNCITRAL's expanded mission gave it a legitimate claim to enter<br />

the field of global lawmakers with a technology that would balance convergence<br />

towards the ideological center with national variation at the global periphery. By<br />

this means, UNCITRAL's organizational adaptations justified its position at the<br />

table of global agents for market regulation. At the same time, it could hold itself<br />

out as responsive to sovereign interests that would likely not subscribe to all<br />

convergent provisions in a set of global norms.<br />

Nevertheless, it is not only the legal technology that displays UNCITRAL's<br />

adroitness in adapting to its various organizational contexts, but also the choice of<br />

"modernization" as a goal. A notion of the "modern" is a social construction. As a<br />

concept, it appears self-validating. Inherent in its meaning are the notions of<br />

progress and development, of advancement and maturity. Paradoxically, part of its<br />

power lies precisely in its vacuity; it is relatively empty of meaning and may, thereby,<br />

be infused with content as circumstances require. For instance, it could mean<br />

something temporal (i.e., it is "modern" simply because it is different from<br />

something older or pre-modern); it could mean something comparative (i.e., this<br />

country claims to be "modern" in comparison to that country which is not); or it<br />

could be functional (i.e., it achieves a "modern" function hitherto missing in a legal<br />

or economic system). We have seen that in practice UNCITRAL uses it in two<br />

ways-"modern" means filling a gap in the law with contemporaneous content ("in<br />

with the new") or replacing former law ("out with the old").<br />

Something of this adeptness in mobilization of the term can be seen within the<br />

Legislative Guide on Insolvency itself. The Guide shows itself to be substantively<br />

modern by adopting an approach to bankruptcy in its policy norms that is consistent<br />

with the world's most powerful economy and perhaps most "modern" nation-the<br />

primacy of reorganization. That the IMF and World Bank-themselves close to the<br />

policy preferences of Washington-also adopt this norm merely reinforces<br />

UNCITRAL's modernizing credentials. Furthermore, we have seen that the Guide<br />

engages in rhetorical gestures that seem intended to underline its "modern"<br />

auspices. Frequently the commentary suggests choices based on modern<br />

developments and trends. Repeatedly the Guide encourages a path of action that<br />

would be consistent with a "modern economy," a "modern insolvency regime," a<br />

"modern commercial law framework," and a "modern, interconnected world." In all<br />

these ways, a very small international organization legitimates itself and its product<br />

through links to powerful nations that label themselves "advanced" and to the<br />

international organizations that urge other nations towards the modernity inherent<br />

in an advanced status.<br />

But it should also be clear that the label of "modernity" relates to power. It is<br />

powerful countries that can adopt the label for themselves and then project their<br />

definition of modernity onto countries they label as not modern. In this sense,<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 513 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:475<br />

UNCITRAL's adoption of the label may be viewed as the appropriation of claims<br />

made by powerful nations and institutions that they stand at the vanguard of<br />

development and, indeed, have the responsibility or even the right to make those<br />

claims pervasive throughout the "unmodern" world. This symbolic alignment of<br />

UNCITRAL with economic and political power thereby earns it an increased<br />

capacity to set global agendas and to earn the respect of global actors for the<br />

"modern" norms it produces.<br />

The very ambiguity in the term "modern" may also serve a useful pragmatic<br />

function. We have argued that UNCITRAL has long recognized the improbability<br />

of far-reaching unification of laws, particularly in contentious policy areas. If widely<br />

relied upon, the Legislative Guide on Insolvency is also likely to be harmonizing at<br />

least in its convergence on reorganization as a policy goal. Beyond this, the<br />

vagueness of "modernization" as a goal allows global convergences around a set of<br />

variations on the global theme such that "modern" insolvency systems might<br />

variously approximate those of the United <strong>State</strong>s, Great Britain, Australia,<br />

Germany, or France, among others-all nations indisputably modern by their own<br />

claims and yet with perceptibly different choices on the options presented by the<br />

Legislative Guide.<br />

As a rhetorical strategy and form of organizational adaptation, therefore,<br />

UNCITRAL's shift away from the goal of unification towards that of modernization<br />

simultaneously solves a number of problems. Insofar as it is conducive to<br />

harmonization, then modernization keeps UNCITRAL faithful to the spirit of its<br />

original mission to facilitate global trade by reducing the divergence of national laws.<br />

Insofar as it seeks to remain a player in the world of global norm making institutions,<br />

modernization provides UNCITRAL the maneuverability to adjust to changing<br />

global agendas. Insofar as UNCITRAL seeks to demonstrate its own relevance, and<br />

that of its parent organization, then modernization gives it reach. And insofar as it<br />

tolerates national diversity around overarching policy objectives, UNCITRAL can<br />

balance its deference to the global center with responsiveness to the global<br />

periphery. All these moves are enabled by the technological inventiveness of the<br />

Legislative Guide on Insolvency.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 514 2006-2007


Property Rights, Collateral, Creditor Rights,<br />

and Insolvency in East Asia'<br />

DOUGLAS W. ARNER,* CHARLES D. BOOTH,** PAUL LEJOT***, & BERRY<br />

F. C. Hsu***<br />

SUMMARY<br />

1. IN T R O D U CT IO N ................................................................................................... 516<br />

II. GOVERNANCE, ECONOMIC AND LEGAL SYSTEMS .......................................... 518<br />

III. THE SIGNIFICANCE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS ...................................................... 524<br />

IV. COLLATERAL AND SECURED TRANSACTIONS ................................................. 525<br />

A . R eal P rop erty ............................................................................................... 530<br />

B. International Standards for Movables ....................................................... 531<br />

C . C ollateral in E ast A sia ................................................................................ 532<br />

1. O verview ............................................................................................... 534<br />

2. R eal P roperty ........................................................................................ 535<br />

D .<br />

3. Movables and Unsecured Property .................................................... 538<br />

Securitizatio n ............................................................................................... 541<br />

V. CREDITOR RIGHTS AND INSOLVENCY .............................................................. 544<br />

A . Inso lven cy .................................................................................................... 544<br />

B. Interaction between Creditor Rights and Insolvency ............................... 546<br />

1. This is an expanded and updated version of a study that was published as Douglas W. Arner,<br />

Charles D. Booth, Berry F. C. Hsu, Paul Lejot, Qiao Liu & Frederik Pretorius, Property Rights, Collateral<br />

and Creditor Rights in East Asia, in EAST ASIAN FINANCE: SELECTED ISSUES (Ismail Dalla ed., World<br />

Bank 2006). The authors thank Dean Polizzotto of the Asian Institute of International Financial <strong>Law</strong> of<br />

the Faculty of <strong>Law</strong> of the University of Hong Kong for research assistance, and the Hong Kong Research<br />

Grants Council Competitive Earmarked Research Grant program and the University of Hong Kong<br />

Strategic Research Areas initiative for financial support.<br />

Associate Professor; Director, Asian Institute of International Financial <strong>Law</strong> (AIIFL); & Director,<br />

LLM (Corporate & Financial <strong>Law</strong>) Program, Faculty of <strong>Law</strong>, University of Hong Kong.<br />

.. Professor & Director, Institute of Asian-Pacific Business <strong>Law</strong>, William S. Richardson School of<br />

<strong>Law</strong>, University of Hawai'i at Manoa.<br />

..* Visiting Fellow, AIIFL, Faculty of <strong>Law</strong>, University of Hong Kong; & Visiting Research Fellow,<br />

ICMA Centre, University of Reading.<br />

.... Associate Professor, Faculty of Architecture, & Deputy Director, AIIFL, Faculty of <strong>Law</strong>,<br />

University of Hong Kong.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 515 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

C. Creditor Rights and Insolvency in East Asia ............................................ 547<br />

1. Insolvency: Pre-1997 O verview ........................................................... 548<br />

2. Insolvency: Post-Financial Crisis Legal Reforms ............................. 551<br />

3. Insolvency: Post-Financial Crisis Out-of-Court Reforms ................ 554<br />

4. Interaction between Creditor Rights and Insolvency ...................... 556<br />

5 . Su m m ary ................................................................................................ 558<br />

VI. CONTRACT ENFORCEMENT AND DISPUTE RESOLUTION ............................... 559<br />

I. INTRODUCTION<br />

A number of common preconditions must prevail if a market-orientated<br />

financial system or national economy is to develop and function effectively. 2 Those<br />

relating to financial sector development rest on three principles: the first,<br />

institutional and legal; the second, largely legal; and the third, related mainly to<br />

policy.<br />

First, a market economy and a market-based financial system cannot exist if<br />

certain institutional and legal supports are not in place, namely, a governance<br />

mechanism that establishes property rights and provides for the consistent<br />

enforcement of contracts and resolution of commercial disputes. It is also important<br />

that the setting provides for the development of human capital. 3<br />

With these institutional foundations in place, a number of legal underpinnings<br />

must then be available for a market-based financial system to function effectively.<br />

These include the availability of collateral to support secured transactions, a system<br />

of law for the establishment and dissolution of corporate bodies, and a transparent<br />

system of government funding, including taxation. To maintain such effectiveness,<br />

national and sub-national governance should also provide more widely for the rule<br />

of law, which is taken to be transparent and non-discriminatory, in addition to<br />

establishing specific property rights, enforcing contracts and supporting commercial<br />

dispute resolution.<br />

Third, a financial sector functions most effectively in the context of appropriate<br />

macroeconomic policies. These policies, while largely outside legal and institutional<br />

concerns, operate best in the context of an appropriately designed and transparent<br />

institutional framework.<br />

No sophisticated market economy or market-based financial system can exist<br />

without these prerequisites, regardless of indigenous or acquired national<br />

characteristics or the form manifested by that system. In this context, this article<br />

examines the relationships within East Asia between economic development,<br />

governance, property rights, provisions for the deployment of collateral and the<br />

creation of secured financial transactions, and creditor rights and their relationship<br />

with insolvency.<br />

2. The framework of analysis underlying this study is based upon DOUGLAS W. ARNER, FINANCIAL<br />

STABILITY, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND THE ROLE OF LAW (2007).<br />

3. Human capital development is not examined here. It became an acknowledged feature of growth<br />

studies with Lucas's 1985 Marshall lectures. See Robert E. Lucas, Jr., On the Mechanics of Economic<br />

Development, 22 J. MONETARY ECON. 1, 17 (1988).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 516 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 517<br />

The eleven subject jurisdictions appear in two groups, shown in Table 1. First is<br />

a core group of nine, which have undergone, or intend to enact, reforms in the<br />

subject areas. Second are two common law jurisdictions that are perceived as being<br />

among the most sophisticated in the region in terms of the issues examined, and<br />

which may represent benchmarks for reform elsewhere. It is not suggested that<br />

either jurisdiction represents an institutional or practical optimum.'<br />

TABLE 1: JURISDICTION CLASSIFICATIONS<br />

Study Core<br />

Regional Benchmarks<br />

Jurisdictions<br />

Cambodia South Korea Hong Kong<br />

China Taiwan Singapore<br />

Indonesia Thailand<br />

Malaysia Vietnam<br />

Philippines<br />

Neither law nor practice is advanced in relevant areas in most of the remaining<br />

jurisdictions within the region, but the issues addressed in this article have begun to<br />

receive attention from policymakers and commercial interests. The issues of policy<br />

and principle raised in this article have been regularly debated in official and legal<br />

circles since the economic and social shocks associated with the 1997-98 Asian<br />

financial crisis. In no national case can the legal, regulatory, or policy background be<br />

described as either complete or fully integrated, even in the two examples of<br />

benchmarks, or elsewhere in countries where specific reforms have been recently<br />

instigated or completed, for example, China or the Philippines.<br />

Later sections include tables that give appraisals of the legal framework for<br />

creditor rights, especially in relation to secured claims; the effectiveness of national<br />

insolvency systems; specific or general provisions for private securitized transactions;<br />

and the mutual compatibility of systems for enforcement. Thus in Tables 2, 5, 7 and<br />

8, a scale rising from 1 to 5 is used to indicate the quality or effectiveness of specific<br />

factors that are self-explanatory, with "NA" used to signify where the law makes no<br />

provision in a specified matter, based primarily upon qualitative analysis. Unless<br />

stated, these tables use terms such as "security" and "interest" in a generic sense<br />

without attachment to any legal system or jurisdiction. In each case, the appraisals<br />

acknowledge not only pure aspects of law and regulation (often clear where the law<br />

includes recent legislation), but also qualifications to reflect enforcement issues,<br />

integration with related law, and the stability of the regulatory setting. Commercial<br />

participants throughout the region have often found that while the law appears clear,<br />

it suffers from uncertain application. The results appear in complex private financial<br />

transactions that seek to mitigate such risks.<br />

It is now generally accepted that the form and practice of law influences<br />

economic behavior. In particular, institutional quality is an important determinant of<br />

4. Certain reforms in Japan's civil code and statutes have guided changes elsewhere among civil law<br />

jurisdictions in the study group. See infra note 80.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 517 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

credit creation and flows of capital, both among the main sectors of an economy and<br />

in cross-border savings and investment. Factors such as legal origin, the nature of<br />

the acquisition or founding of law, and details of its application and enforcement are<br />

seen in features of governance, economic systems and structure, commercial culture,<br />

corporate behavior, and financing patterns. These conditions also affect broader<br />

variables such as national output or personal income. The appraisals in this article<br />

and the research upon which they are based thus adopt the view of users, that is,<br />

principals and agents, that become subject to the law rather than those involved in its<br />

creation or administration.<br />

At the same time, the efficiency and consistency of the law's operation will<br />

always form part of its institutional costs, so that no assessment can ignore the<br />

organization and management of legal systems. This is especially valid in the context<br />

of creditor claims and corporate distress. In general, the main objective of the<br />

reform of laws governing security and creditor rights will be to influence behavior<br />

through changes in costs. The following two parts of this article discuss respectively,<br />

its theoretical background and the role of property rights in transaction formation<br />

and credit creation. Parts IV and V then examine collateral and secured<br />

transactions, and creditor rights and insolvency, respectively. Part VI concludes with<br />

an outline of provisions in Asia for contract enforcement and commercial dispute<br />

resolution.<br />

II.<br />

GOVERNANCE, ECONOMIC AND LEGAL SYSTEMS<br />

<strong>State</strong> governance and the appropriateness of political and economic structure<br />

have been of interest for over ten thousand years, prompted by specialized human<br />

activity encouraging the first agricultural settlements. This in turn allowed the<br />

development of writing systems appropriate and necessary to sustain the<br />

administrative structures of such settlements. Building the "perfect society" and<br />

creating governance systems to encourage its development has been a focus of many<br />

thinkers, including Confucius, Plato, Aquinas, Locke, and Marx. All political and<br />

economic systems function in close parallel, even though the interplay may not<br />

always be acknowledged by political theorists. Certainly, the relationship between<br />

politics (or governance) and economics has been a central interest of Smith, Marx,<br />

and more recently Keynes, Hayek, and Friedman. Although politics and economics<br />

became increasingly distinct disciplines in the twentieth century, the end of the<br />

millennium saw a reviving interaction between governance and economics, partly<br />

encouraged by the experience of market orientation undertaken by many centrally<br />

planned economies, and from the conspicuous failure of earlier economic<br />

development models in neglecting institutional issues of governance.<br />

The role and development of financial intermediaries have become a focus of<br />

attention only recently in law, financial policy, and economics, although each<br />

discipline is directly concerned with both the problem and its several explanations.<br />

Similarly, conditions influencing how financial structure develops have begun to<br />

interest scholars in the developed and developing world, and those helping to create<br />

supportive policy. Until the 1970s few economic or finance theorists gave attention<br />

to the nature of financial systems or how they may affect economic development.<br />

Similarly, the importance and influence of the characteristics of financial markets<br />

and intermediaries has been accepted only since the late-1980s, with the inception<br />

and success of the law and finance and institutional economics schools. Financial<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 518 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 519<br />

intermediation is now recognized as vital to many aspects of economic development,<br />

and what determines the nature of financial intermediaries and financial system<br />

infrastructure is susceptible to both quantitative analysis and the tools of legal and<br />

economic theory.<br />

By the beginning of the 1990s, two traditionally polar alternatives-central<br />

planning under state ownership and laissez-faire-had been subsumed into an<br />

apparent consensus as to the general superiority of a market economy, but one<br />

functioning under the framework of an appropriate and transparent regulatory<br />

system, with the state taking a benign but active role in addressing the interests of<br />

any society through the provision of largely agreed public goods, systems to limit or<br />

ameliorate market failure, and sanctions to penalize market abuse, whether arising<br />

from monopoly or the occurrence of asymmetric information available to privileged<br />

participants. Nonetheless, as Shleifer and others have recognized, many differences<br />

remain among today's economic and governance models.' The question then arises<br />

as to what may represent the best choices among available options, and to what<br />

extent those choices lead to the disadvantage of certain interests.<br />

For institutional economists such as North, and writers in the law and<br />

economics school, governance systems must provide for two fundamental features to<br />

support a market economy, regardless of its ideological identity and consequent<br />

form. First, the system must provide for clear and usable property rights. Second, it<br />

must facilitate practical and fair contract enforcement. Both literatures agree that<br />

these conditions are essential in the context of imperfect markets where there exist<br />

discernable transaction costs. While there appears to be agreement as to the need to<br />

satisfy these basic points, the governance structure that best supports a market<br />

economy is less apparent, and may change in relation to the relative development of<br />

the host economy.<br />

Many scholars have argued further that democratic models of governance are<br />

optimal in protecting property rights and enforcing contracts, albeit this was the<br />

result they sought most often to prove. However, Olson has presented a convincing<br />

argument that a variety of governance structures can provide each of these necessary<br />

features. 6 Specifically, he suggested that an autocrat with a long-term time horizon<br />

will have a strong incentive to support both property rights and contract<br />

enforcement in order chiefly to maximize revenue from taxation. 7 Conversely, Olson<br />

argues that any democracy, while potentially providing for property rights and the<br />

enforcement of contracts, may nevertheless become subject to inefficient outcomes<br />

due to its responsiveness to representative but factional interests. 8 Thus neither<br />

autocracy nor democracy is necessarily a superior political system in providing the<br />

most beneficial support for a market economy. Instead, what is necessary is a<br />

"market-augmenting government." 9 There is contemporary anecdotal evidence that<br />

5. See Simeon Djankov et al., The New Comparative Economics, 31 J. COMP. ECON. 595 (2003).<br />

6. MANCUR OLSON, POWER AND PROSPERITY: OUTGROWING COMMUNIST AND CAPITALIST<br />

DICTATORSHIPS (2000).<br />

7. Id.<br />

8. Id.<br />

9. Charles Cadwell, Foreword to MANCUR OLSON, OUTGROWING COMMUNIST AND CAPITALIST<br />

DICTATORSHIPS, at x (2000).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 519 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

certainly supports Olson's theory,' and recent empirical research has begun to test<br />

these ideas and appears to be supportive."<br />

North sums up the interaction between the political system and property rights<br />

thus:<br />

Broadly speaking, political rules in place lead to economic rules, though<br />

the causality runs both ways. That is, property rights and hence individual<br />

contracts are specified and enforced by political decision-making, but the<br />

structure of economic interests will also influence the political structure.<br />

In equilibrium, a given structure of property rights (and their<br />

enforcement) will be consistent with a particular set of political rules (and<br />

their enforcement). Changes in one will induce changes in the other. 2<br />

The result is that a national governance structure is important and must provide<br />

for property rights and the enforcement of contracts, as well as human capital<br />

development. However, while some governance structures are clearly not conducive<br />

to liberty (any state run by the myopic autocrat-bandit), there is at present no clearly<br />

preferable model. Both autocratic and democratic governance systems can support<br />

a market economy. Similarly, each can provide for institutional choices that fail to<br />

result in efficient, wealth-maximizing outcomes in a given economy.<br />

Two further underlying issues are present throughout this study: those relating<br />

to the mechanisms that transmit influences on economic growth, and those involving<br />

the means by which finance affects economic development, including the<br />

relationship between legal systems and financial structure. Neoclassical economic<br />

theory, post-1940s growth theories and traditional finance theory all ignore or<br />

assume away the nature of financial systems." While finance and corporate finance<br />

theory examine commercial organizations in terms of contract or cost, a similar<br />

approach has been applied only recently to financial intermediaries, and rarely to<br />

examine financial systems. Thus, early modern studies of the determinants of<br />

economic growth identified a strong correlation between the "rule of law" and per<br />

capita growth.'" These analyses were weak in terms of identifying with any practical<br />

precision the ways in which legal reform might be invoked to promote growth, given<br />

10. Cf. China, Singapore.<br />

11. See Djankov et al., supra note 5 (indicating that policies are more important than democratic<br />

institutions, and specifically, that human capital is a more basic source of growth than democratic<br />

institutions; that poorer states can alleviate poverty through sound policies, even when pursued by<br />

dictators; democratic institutions are developed after economic "take-off").<br />

12. DOUGLASS C. NORTH, INSTITUTIONS, INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE, AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE<br />

48 (1990).<br />

13. This growth school pattern probably began with WALTER ROSTOW, THE PROCESS OF ECONOMIC<br />

GROWTH (1952); Lucas, supra note 3, perhaps the most willful financial agnostic, based indifference upon<br />

the thesis that at firm level, financial performance is unrelated to the composition of funding. Certain<br />

Marxian analysis asserts a causal relationship running from economic activity to financial structure to<br />

accord with the primacy of capitalist production. It is often unspecific in its treatment of both law and<br />

financial activity in this area, perhaps reflecting Marx's disdain for "merchant" or "commercial" capital an<br />

exception is J. J. McManus The Emergence and Non-emergence of <strong>Law</strong>, 5 BRIT. J. LAW & SOC'Y 185. 190<br />

(1978) (describing the origin of English consumer credit legislation).<br />

14. Notably, Robert J. Barro, Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries, 106 Q. J. ECON. 26-28<br />

(1971); ROBERT J. BARRO, DETERMINANTS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CROSS-COUNTRY EMPIRICAL<br />

STUDY 26-28 (1997).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 520 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 521<br />

that the measures used to specify rule of law explanatory variables were primitive<br />

and included subjective components such as commercial indexes of sovereign risk.<br />

The law and finance school asserts that there exist significant causal links<br />

between the origins of law or the means by which a national system of law is<br />

acquired, and the nature of financial system development. 15 Certain scholars further<br />

suggest a causal relationship that flows from financial development to economic<br />

performance, although most accept that such links are unlikely to be unicausal 6<br />

Questions investigated or prompted by the law and finance school include: first, the<br />

relationship of institutional development to general economic welfare; second, the<br />

relationship between legal origin and the effectiveness and even-handedness of legal<br />

systems; third, whether the effectiveness of a national legal system is significantly<br />

determined by its origin or the form of its acquisition; and finally, whether common<br />

law is inherently more effective than other systems in encouraging financial<br />

development, stimulating credit growth or protecting property rights. 7<br />

While the general premise of law and finance protagonists has become<br />

accepted, especially in suggesting more specific legal research agendas, the school<br />

has been criticized for two main methodological reasons. The first is its choice and<br />

specification of explanatory variables:" 8 which may either be incomplete or<br />

endogenously related to the objective questions that the analysis seeks to answer;"<br />

which may not signify close substitutes or take account of compensatory mechanisms<br />

in different legal systems; 0 or may reflect customary choice appropriate mainly to<br />

15. Djankov et al., supra note 5; Robert G. King & Ross Levine, Finance & Growth: Schumpeter<br />

Might Be Right, 108 Q. J. ECON. 717 (1993), Ross Levine, Finance & Growth: Theory & Evidence (Nat'l<br />

Bureau of Econ. Res. Working Paper No. 10766, 2004); Ross Levine, Financial Development and<br />

Economic Growth: Views and Agenda, 35 J. ECON. LIT. 688 (1997); Raghuram G. Rajan & Luigi Zingales,<br />

Financial Systems, Industrial Structure, and Growth, 17 OXFORD REV. ECON. POL. 467 (2001).<br />

16. Notably Thorsten Beck et al., <strong>Law</strong> and Finance: Why Does Legal Origin Matter? (World Bank<br />

Pol'y Res. Working Paper 2904, 2002); Thorsten Beck & Ross Levine, Legal Institutions and Financial<br />

Development (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res. Working Paper No. 10126, 2003); Rafael La Porta et al., <strong>Law</strong><br />

and Finance, 106 J. POL. ECON. 1113 (1998); Legal Determinants of External Finance, 52 J. FIN. 1131 (1997);<br />

Paul G. Mahoney, The Common <strong>Law</strong> and Economic Analysis: Hayek Might be Right, 30 J. LEGAL STUD.<br />

503 (2001); Peter L. Rousseau & Richard Sylla, Financial Systems, Economic Growth and Globalization<br />

(Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res. Working Paper No. 8323, 2001).<br />

17. Given that the quality of creditor and shareholder protection measures the effectiveness of a<br />

national legal system. This is not synonymous with financial development but is often so taken, with the<br />

protection of claims used as a proxy for financial sophistication.<br />

18. Philip Arestis & Panicos Demetriadis, Financial Development & Economic Growth: Assessing the<br />

Evidence, 107 ECON. J. 783 (1997): Daniel Berkowitz et al., The Transplant Effect, 51 AM. J. COMP. L. 163<br />

(2003); David Blum et al., The Financial-Real Sector Nexus: Theory & Empirical Evidence (Res. Inst. for<br />

European Affairs Working Paper No. 43, 2002); Charles Kenny & David Williams, What do we know about<br />

Economic Growth? Or, Why don't we know very much?, 29 WORLD DEV. 1 (2001); Michael Thiel, Finance<br />

& Economic Growth: A Review of Theory & the Available Evidence (Eur. Comm. Econ. Pap. No. 158,<br />

2001); Paul Wachtel, How much do we really know about Growth & Finance?, 88 FED. RES. BANK<br />

ATLANTA ECON. REV. 1 (2003).<br />

19. See Rajan, supra note 15.<br />

20. MARK J. ROE, STRONG MANAGERS, WEAK OWNERS: THE POLITICAL ROOTS OF AMERICAN<br />

CORPORATE FINANCE (1994); KATHARINA PISTOR & PHILIP WELLONS, THE ROLE OF LAW AND LEGAL<br />

INSTITUTIONS IN ASIAN ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1960-1995 (1999); Katharina Pistor et al., <strong>Law</strong> and<br />

Finance in Transition Economies, (European Bank for Reconstruction & Dev. Working Paper No. 48,<br />

2000); Sofie Cools, The Real Difference in Corporate <strong>Law</strong> Between the United <strong>State</strong>s and Continental<br />

Europe: Distribution or Powers, 30 DEL. J. CORP. L. 697 (2005); Mathias Siems, Legal Origins: Reconciling<br />

<strong>Law</strong> & Finance And Comparative <strong>Law</strong>, available at SSRN: http://ssrn.comnabstract=920690.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 521 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

developed, homogenous markets. 2 The second attack concerns the usefulness of the<br />

school's conclusions in indicating legal or regulatory reform, given that legal related<br />

explanatory variables have of necessity been general and unspecific. 22<br />

As examples, the scale of finance evident in an economy has often been used as<br />

an explanatory variable, but it may not measure financial sophistication, contrary to<br />

the intentions of La Porta, L6pez-de-Silanes, Shleifer & Vishny (LLSV) or Rousseau<br />

& Sylla; 23 no distinction is made between types of claims against a debtor or firm.<br />

Rather, all debt is generally taken as secured. The chain of causation identified by<br />

the law and finance school (especially LLSV) runs from legal origin to enforcement,<br />

to financial development and finally to growth. This is unreliable for policy<br />

development if legality impacts growth but legal origin does not impact legality. A<br />

more fully informed identification of explanatory variables will assist with these<br />

problems. It may also overcome problems caused by the static nature of the law and<br />

finance school's analysis, for example, ignoring the convergence of civil and common<br />

commercial law with political regionalization and financial harmonization, more<br />

extensive financial and trade treaty networks, and the activity of international selfregulatory<br />

bodies.<br />

Theoretical interest in the structure and operation of financial systems was<br />

largely absent from legal and financial studies before the 1970s, and in schools of<br />

24<br />

economics was confined to political economy. That such indifference has vanished<br />

results largely from the influence of two trains of scholars. First, Goldsmith sought<br />

ways to test whether financial structure could be related to levels of economic<br />

development." This work was to become a foundation of the law and finance school.<br />

Second, North and others synthesized hitherto separate concepts from law, finance<br />

and economics in what has become modern institutional economics, which stresses<br />

the nature and effect of core rights, duties and incentives. While the first is primarily<br />

concerned with whole markets or national economies and the latter is initially<br />

microeconomic in its emphasis, the two disciplines share certain interests, and meet<br />

in the analysis of the effects of legal systems and property rights, for example, on<br />

economic conditions and development.<br />

The approach of the traditional financial development school was to examine<br />

the role of banking and bank credit creation. More recent law and finance analysis<br />

has taken account of environmental and cultural factors, and indeed all measurable<br />

financial variables. None has yet examined in detail the quality of law enforcement<br />

in a commercial context, for example, in the willingness of national courts to enforce<br />

foreign judgments and accept non-exclusive jurisdiction transaction provisions.<br />

Instead, where quality of law and regulation is included in analysis, its tendency to<br />

date has been on subjective index measures of the "rule of law." In addition, while<br />

law and finance scholars have sought to quantify the effects on financial<br />

21. Naomi R. Lamoreaux & Jean-Lamoreaux Rosenthal, Legal Regime and Business Organizational<br />

Choice: A Comparison of France and the United <strong>State</strong>s (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res. Working Paper No.<br />

10288, 2004).<br />

22. Frank B. Cross, <strong>Law</strong> and Economic Growth, 80 TEx. L. REV. 1736 (2002); Kevin E. Davis, What<br />

Can the Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Variable Tell Us About Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Reforms? (N.Y.U. L. & Econ. Res. Paper Series<br />

Working Paper No. 04-026, 2004); Kevin E. Davis & Michael J. Trebilcock, Legal Reforms and<br />

Development, 22 THIRD WORLD 0. 210 (2001); Roe, supra note 20.<br />

23. See supra note 16.<br />

24. Due largely to Marx, Schumpeter, and Weber and their later acolytes, but in no instance with the<br />

dedication to detail of the modern law and finance school.<br />

25. RAYMOND GOLDSMITH, FINANCIAL STRUCTURE AND DEVELOPMENT (1969).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 522 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 523<br />

development of national legal systems or their origins, 26 no systematic attempt has<br />

yet appeared in this context that together considers legal origins, their form of<br />

acquisition and the distinct nature of jurisdictions, especially when their roots are<br />

mixed. 2 ' Nor has analysis yet recognized that the nature of commercial legal disputes<br />

may itself be endogenous to the legal system.<br />

Related work includes a considerable body of empirical studies in the style<br />

pioneered by Goldsmith and following the methods adopted by King & Levine and<br />

LLSV in seeking evidence of causal relationships between financial market or<br />

institutional sophistication or structure (including legal origins and conditions), and<br />

economic development, commonly measured by growth in national output. While<br />

not unanimous, these generally suggest that finance often has a positive effect on<br />

growth, although contrary to popular belief there is no theoretical school that asserts<br />

the contrary: that the primary causal flow is from economic growth to financial<br />

development. 28<br />

The remainder of this article contains summaries of appraisals of the<br />

effectiveness of current law and practice as to collateral and creditor rights in eleven<br />

prominent East Asian jurisdictions. In particular, it examines discrete aspects of the<br />

creation and treatment of secured creditor interests, processes for insolvency,<br />

securitization, and the functional relationship between these related aspects of law.<br />

The effects of globalization on both market practice and harmonization of financial<br />

regulation mean that the private law governing international financial transactions<br />

differs less by virtue of the location of parties or the place of transaction execution<br />

than by issues of judicial enforcement, including the willingness of courts to provide<br />

equitable and predictable judgments to domestic and foreign creditors." The quality<br />

of legal and practical provisions for insolvency is also central to the willingness of<br />

lenders and investors to provide funds for capital investment. By contrast, legal<br />

frameworks for the taking or enforcement of collateral may be influenced by<br />

informal or traditional national or local commercial custom, although remaining<br />

subject also to the prevailing form of law and the roots of national law.<br />

26. See La Porta et al., supra note 16 (classifying forty-nine national legal systems by their origins in<br />

English common law or French, German or "Scandinavian" civil law); Berkowitz et al., supra note 18<br />

(dividing the same sample among ten original systems); PHILIP WOOD, COMPARATIVE FINANCIAL LAW<br />

(1995) (perceiving seven categories, not including states that lack a clear legal system or for which it may<br />

be "emerging"). Earlier comparatists found different solutions, the most contemporary being David, who<br />

identifies eight "families" of law, see RENt DAVID & JOHN E. C. BRIERLEY, MAJOR LEGAL SYSTEMS IN<br />

THE WORLD TODAY: AN INTRODUCTION TO THE COMPARATIVE STUDY OF LAW (John E. C. Brierley<br />

trans., 2d ed. 1978), not all of which subsist in the form described.<br />

27. Philip Wood, Global <strong>Law</strong> Maps: Key Map of Jurisdictions (mimeo, 2001) identified up to 307<br />

distinct national and state jurisdictions. The number is certain to change.<br />

28. That a body of scholarship contends that financial development largely responds to economic<br />

growth was first suggested against the theme of his study by Richard C. Porter, The Promotion of the<br />

"Banking Habit" and Economic Development, 2 J. DEV. STUD. 346, 363 (1966) (asserting in a footnote that<br />

"the few economists who have proposed a clear direction of causation between real and financial growth<br />

usually suggest [that real growth precedes financial sector development]"). The remark is often repeated<br />

without substantiation.<br />

29. This appears in contemporary comparative analyses of commercial law. See WOOD, supra note<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 523 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

III. THE SIGNIFICANCE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS<br />

Property rights were an important concern for Smith, Marx and Weber but<br />

received little attention from economists for generations until becoming subject to<br />

intensive research in the late 1970s. Until recently the nature of finance and thus the<br />

preconditions for its provision were ignored or assumed away by generations of<br />

economists and finance specialists; only "maverick" opinion appears to have<br />

considered otherwise.<br />

The importance of property rights began to receive significant contemporary<br />

attention when the disintegration of the Soviet bloc introduced the challenge of<br />

transforming command economies to market-based systems. Development specialist<br />

de Soto deserves considerable credit for increasing awareness of the importance of<br />

property rights in this respect, especially in relation to the potential impact of<br />

formally endowing individuals with such rights.<br />

Classically, property is seen as a "bundle of rights." More specifically,<br />

"property" includes some or all of a variety of different "rights," including the rights<br />

to hold, use, modify, transfer, or destroy a real or intangible asset. Questions of<br />

degree and time relate to all such varied rights, and the extent to which a property<br />

owner may exploit such rights may be constrained by the competing rights of others<br />

within a legal system or as part of public policy. In addition, property can be real or<br />

personal, tangible, or intangible. The more complex a system of property rights, the<br />

more effective is their potential use in the context of finance and capital-raising.<br />

According to North:<br />

Property rights are the rights individuals appropriate over their own labor<br />

and the goods and services they possess. Appropriation is a function of<br />

legal rules, organizational forms, enforcement, and norms of behaviorthat<br />

is, the institutional framework. 3 "<br />

De Soto argues that capital is the engine of a market economy, with property<br />

rights the mechanism that allows it to be effectively deployed. 31 Further, relatively<br />

poor countries often fail to produce capital sufficient for economic development due<br />

to five main failings in property systems. First, such societies may have substantial<br />

masses of capital, 32 yet it represents "dead" resources in that it is constituted by<br />

assets, interests or claims that cannot be used or mobilized as capital. Second,<br />

capital is intrinsically difficult to define or recognize. Third, many states have<br />

neglected the importance of the preceding two factors, an attitude that has begun<br />

only slowly to change. 33 Fourth, while de Soto's process of mobilizing property rights<br />

30. DOUGLASS NORTH, INSTITUTIONS, INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 33<br />

(1990).<br />

31. HERNANDO DE SOTO, THE MYSTERY OF CAPITAL: WHY CAPITALISM TRIUMPHS IN THE WEST<br />

AND FAILS EVERYWHERE ELSE (2000).<br />

32. Id. at 35. By his calculation, "the total value of the real estate held but not legally owned by the<br />

poor of the Third World and former communist nations is at least [US]$ 9.3 trillion." Id.<br />

33. De Soto states this best:<br />

The substantial increase of capital in the West over the past two centuries is the consequence of<br />

gradually improving property systems, which allowed economic agents to discover and realize<br />

the potential in their assets, and thus to be in a position to produce the non-inflationary money<br />

with which to finance and generate additional production.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 524 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 525<br />

needed in emerging or transition economies had occurred earlier elsewhere, it was<br />

often poorly understood or documented, even in relatively sophisticated states.<br />

Finally, laws need to reflect national or local circumstances in order to allow the<br />

effective transformation of property rights into capital.<br />

For de Soto:<br />

A well-integrated legal property system in essence does two things: First,<br />

it tremendously reduces the costs of knowing the economic qualities of<br />

assets by representing them in a way that our senses can pick up quickly;<br />

and second, it facilitates the capacity to agree on how to use assets to<br />

create further production and increase the division of labor."<br />

De Soto concludes that formal property systems are required to produce six<br />

effects so as to allow individuals to generate usable capital. These are: first, making<br />

certain the economic potential of existing assets; second, integrating dispersed<br />

information into a single dependable system; third, making individuals accountable<br />

for their economic actions; fourth, increasing the fungibility of assets; fifth,<br />

marshalling individuals into valuable social networks; and sixth, protecting the<br />

integrity of legitimate transactions."<br />

Established and accepted property rights and their identification and<br />

protection, including rights over intellectual property are, therefore, essential in any<br />

market economy. 36 Unfortunately, de Soto notes that such rights have evolved in<br />

advanced economies over protracted periods, making it difficult even for the legal<br />

historian to discern how they function or become established. Without complete<br />

templates of this kind it may never be simple for emerging, transition or developing<br />

economies to introduce those experiences or systems, even when respecting the<br />

integrity of local or state culture. Furthermore, the recognition of property rights is<br />

not self-justifying; the need is for such rights to be available for use other than in<br />

instantly completed transactions. This is an underlying theme of the remainder of<br />

this article.<br />

IV.<br />

COLLATERAL AND SECURED TRANSACTIONS<br />

Collateral exists to meet commercial customs, national practices, and socioeconomic<br />

constraints that differ strongly between jurisdictions, even in an era when<br />

commercial practice and financial regulation are often well-integrated and the<br />

international harmonization of financial markets is well-advanced. Several World<br />

Bank studies have surveyed law, institutions, and secured transactions, 37 but the<br />

reasons for security differ everywhere by intention, nature, and degree. This affects<br />

whether the granting of collateral is an efficient choice for commercial or individual<br />

Id. at 65.<br />

34. Id. at 63.<br />

35. Id. at 49-62.<br />

36. Leora Kapper et al., Business Environment and Firm Entry: Evidence from International Data 27-<br />

28 (World Bank Policy Research, Working Paper No. 3232, 2004).<br />

37. See World Bank, 1989 World Bank Dev. Rep. (1989); 2002 World Bank Dev. Rep. (2002); Yoram<br />

Keinan, The Evolution of Secured Transaction's Background Study for World Development Report 2002<br />

(2001).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 525 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

borrowers, or for creditors at large. Recent analysis of European transition<br />

economies suggests that the provision of collateral is important in inducing earlystage<br />

development."<br />

Schumpeter's 1939 description of the working of capitalism 39 draws on his<br />

earlier theoretical approach to interest and credit creation that came to be disputed<br />

by contemporary traditional classicists (Cannan), radicals (Keynes and Joan<br />

Robinson), and for some remains controversial. It includes a generic description of<br />

the role of credit creation in banking not attempted by his contemporary critics.<br />

Schumpeter's approach includes a customary means by which a creditor bank may<br />

seek to overcome transaction obstacles and thus lessen the costs resulting from<br />

asymmetric information, which otherwise would often force the adoption of<br />

incomplete lending contracts. Modern structured finance techniques such as nonrecourse<br />

project finance or securitization are intended to limit to the greatest<br />

possible extent the incompleteness of financing contracts. In each case, contractual<br />

structuring results in the debtor having no surplus value, so as to become<br />

theoretically constrained from engaging in activity outside the financed enterprise.<br />

By contrast, lending conducted under typical incomplete contracts involves<br />

credit risks subject to unquantifiable Knightian uncertainty, since lenders can only be<br />

partially informed as to the scope of activities of companies to which they lend.<br />

Even though lenders may hope to mitigate the effects of incomplete contracts by<br />

incorporating covenants and assignments of actual or potential revenue into<br />

contracts, the result will inevitably be subject to general practice and comparative<br />

strengths in negotiation. Even if a lender has full knowledge of a debtor enterprise,<br />

the volition of the debtor may lead to default, which on occasion may be<br />

economically rational.' Other mechanisms to encourage contract compliance (given<br />

that few non-fraudulent debtors in advanced economies now face the threat of<br />

prison) include socioeconomic forces of the kind traditionally associated with distinct<br />

lending markets, for example, in the financing of the trade in diamonds or ship<br />

purchase. By this view, the taking of collateral is thus not related to information<br />

discontinuities but represents a sanction to encourage contract compliance by the<br />

debtor. In terms of institutional analysis it will typically constitute a distortion,<br />

38. Rainer Haselmann, Katharina Pistor & Vikrant Vig, How <strong>Law</strong> Affects Lending (Colum. L. Econ.<br />

Working Paper No. 285, 2005). By contrast, this may not have been the case in the British industrial<br />

revolution, when the existence of reliable non-possessory land mortgages failed to induce banks to lend in<br />

a major way to industrial capitalists, allowing historians to discount the importance of finance in<br />

development; see MAURICE DOBB, STUDIES IN THE DEVELOPMENT OF CAPITALISM (1947); MICHAEL<br />

FLINN, ORIGINS OF THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION (1966) 52-53. A similar pattern of bank passivity is<br />

observed in the United <strong>State</strong>s at the turn of the twentieth century; see Naomi R, Lamoreaux, Margaret<br />

Levenstein & Kenneth L. Sokoloff, Financing Invention during the Second Industrial Revolution: Cleveland<br />

Ohio 1870-1920, 27-30 (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res. Working Paper No. 10923, 2004). Yet only after 1850<br />

did a reliable form of non-possessory chattel mortgage emerge in Britain, and it was arguably not fully<br />

trusted by lenders until the early twentieth century. ROY GOODE, COMMERCIAL LAW 586 (3d ed. 2004).<br />

Neal observes that England's preceding seventeenth to eighteenth century "financial revolution" has long<br />

been underestimated in its effect on later commercial development, see Larry Neal, The Finance of<br />

Business during the Industrial Revolution, in 1 THE ECONOMIC HISTORY OF BRITAIN SINCE 1700, 151<br />

(Roderick Floud & Deirdre McCloskey eds.(1994). Hartwell similarly acknowledges a lack of attention to<br />

private finance in growth studies, describing the service sector as the "neglected variable"; see RONALD<br />

MAX HARTWELL, THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH (1971).<br />

39. JOSEPH SCHUMPETER, BUSINESS CYCLES: A THEORETICAL, HISTORICAL, AND STATISTICAL<br />

ANALYSIS OF THE CAPITALIST PROCESS (1939).<br />

40. For example, in the case of home mortgage loans where the value of collateral falls below the<br />

amounts outstanding, given certain limits to creditor rights in bankruptcy.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 526 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 527<br />

enabling credit substitution to become the means by which a bank lender avoids the<br />

moral hazard associated with asymmetric information.<br />

At the same time, contrary to the findings of certain studies of domestic U.S.<br />

practice-except in cases where recourse to the principal debtor is non-existent or<br />

limited-taking security is not generally a device to signal credit quality but the<br />

converse, 4 ' as with conventional non-recourse project finance. Rather, it serves three<br />

main purposes for the principals involved or prospectively engaged in financial<br />

bargaining, shown in Figure 1.<br />

FIGURE 1: PRINCIPAL FUNCTIONS OF COLLATERAL<br />

(A)<br />

financier.<br />

Transformative<br />

(B)<br />

Informative<br />

(C)<br />

(D)<br />

(E)<br />

Providing incentives<br />

(F)<br />

(G)<br />

(H)<br />

Mitigation or substitution in credit risk for a potential<br />

Change in capital asset use to make financing available.<br />

Signal credit risk strengths or borrower status.<br />

Signal risk or bargaining weaknesses.<br />

Facilitate credit substitution.<br />

Effect on costs and information for credit creation.<br />

Provide financiers with known credit risks.<br />

Encourage contractual compliance by collateral providers.<br />

Adequate institutional infrastructure enable banks to extend the duration of<br />

their loans and reduce regulatory capital costs by providing greater confidence as to<br />

the credit risk associated with likelihood of repayment. In this regard, two aspects of<br />

lending infrastructure are especially important for risk management: an effective<br />

system for taking security, and sufficient sources of information through accounting<br />

standards, audit practice, credit rating methodology and oversight, and acceptable<br />

credit information systems. In addition, banks need systems to manage risks<br />

appropriately, these typically being required by capital adequacy and other<br />

prudential regulatory requirements.<br />

41. This and other motivations for borrowers to grant security have been questioned notably by<br />

Schwartz, who (assuming with Modigliani and Miller that the value of an enterprise is unrelated to the<br />

composition of its capital) asks whether security represents an efficient practice, given its effect on other<br />

potential creditors and the interplay of priority of claims with U.S. precepts of bankruptcy. See Alan<br />

Schwartz, Security Interests and Bankruptcy Priorities: A Review of Current Theories, 10 J. LEGAL STUD. 1,<br />

1 (1981) [hereinafter Schwartz, Security Interests]; Alan Schwartz, The Continuing Puzzle of Secured Debt,<br />

37 VAND. L.R. 5, 1051 (1984) [hereinafter Schwartz, Puzzle of Secured Debt]; Franco Modigliani & Merton<br />

Miller, The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment, 48 AM. ECON. REV. 261<br />

(1958). A more recent study suggests that collateral provides incentives for lenders to monitor loan<br />

performance and is correlated with generally poor business conditions or the debtor's financial distress.<br />

See Raghuram Rajan & Andrew Winton, Covenants and Collateral as Incentives to Monitor, 50 J. FIN. 1113<br />

(1995).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 527 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

As an institution of risk management, an effective system to create security<br />

allows lenders to obtain collateral to reduce unwanted credit risk and have<br />

confidence that such collateral may be realized where necessary to permit the full or<br />

partial repayment of a loan. Effective security creation and registration thus<br />

provides two advantages for lenders. First, it allows the limiting of monitoring costs<br />

by means of partial or complete credit risk substitution, providing that no failure to<br />

monitor collateral results in the erosion of security protection. Second, it increases<br />

simplicity in lending decision-making, thereby increasing the probability that such<br />

decisions will be made. 42<br />

If property rights are to create capital, they must be applied to procure funding<br />

so that the taking of security is the lender's simplest form of risk mitigation. Loans<br />

are disbursed provided the lender is given a contingent claim to property of a<br />

proportionately equivalent or greater value. If the debt is not satisfied, the lender<br />

retains the property and need take little or no account of the credit risk of the<br />

borrower. In this simple case, the availability of collateral induces marginal lending.<br />

However, to prompt this simple transaction, the lender must be confident of<br />

retaining rights to the property given contractual non-payment by the debtor. Thus,<br />

the borrower must have valid initial title to the property, and the law must provide<br />

for certain and effective transfer of ownership in the event of the security being<br />

enforced. Finally, the lender will need a means to appraise supporting collateral.<br />

This has often been a problematic feature of all economies, whether developed,<br />

emerging, transition, or developing, and usually in the context of loans secured by<br />

real property.<br />

Complex collateral-based lending involves sophisticated distinctions between<br />

property rights and the certainty of contractual enforcement, derived from the<br />

prevailing legal and institutional framework. For example, in the simple transaction<br />

of the preceding paragraph, a borrower provided physical, recognizable collateral to<br />

secure its indebtedness, as in the common South Asian example of personal loans<br />

secured by quantities of gold or silver. This is collateral deployed in its most simple<br />

form. For reasons presented in the preceding paragraphs, the use of collateral in<br />

secured transactions can become more complex only to the extent that it is<br />

supported by an adequate legal and institutional framework. If a borrower must<br />

deliver physical collateral to a lender then poorly capitalized enterprises will lack<br />

access to most secured lending, and excessive transaction costs render the exercise<br />

sub-optimal.<br />

With institutional support for more advanced practices, a borrower may be<br />

allowed physical possession of collateral pre-dating the creation of a new loan, thus<br />

keeping day-to-day control of the use and enterprise value of existing assets,<br />

whether land, buildings, plant, or machinery. At a still more sophisticated legal<br />

level, a loan might be used to purchase real property or productive assets, secured by<br />

those newly-acquired assets, with the borrower retaining their full use in ways that<br />

may be expected to assist in the servicing of the loan. While the mechanics of such<br />

transactions are simple to describe, this type of purchase money security is not<br />

universally supported by security or bankruptcy law. Whether national law allows or<br />

42. The contrary argument is that over-reliance on collateral in lending to commercial enterprises<br />

represents an inefficient solution and raises a moral hazard, in each case by disassociating the creditor from<br />

a true interest in the borrower's commercial prospects. Even if this is not the case, in certain common law<br />

jurisdictions where banks may be encouraged to seek security interests in order to gain a degree of<br />

contractual influence over the debtor.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 528 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 529<br />

limits such arrangements reflects an underlying view of the economic welfare<br />

associated with security and collateral. This is seen in the competing views of a<br />

commercial enterprise as being either revenue generating or a custodian of assets,<br />

and may result in the legal treatment of the purchase of money security as unfairly<br />

benefiting individual creditors at the expense of others. 3<br />

In each case, transaction complexity requires greater legal sophistication, and<br />

deploying moveable property as collateral typically requires a more complex legal<br />

framework than real property. Furthermore, while real or movable physical<br />

collateral is associated with the largest share of secured lending in most emerging<br />

and developed economies, intangible property may also represent potential<br />

collateral, including intellectual property or trade receivables. The rights of a<br />

secured creditor could thus extend to defined classes of assets such as inventory or<br />

receivables, to a company's entire asset base if it becomes subject to whole business<br />

securitization, or where debts are secured by floating charges as found in English law<br />

and certain other common law jurisdictions. They might also extend to the right to<br />

receive revenues rather than actual receipt of revenues, providing in each case that<br />

the institutional system is sufficiently supportive.<br />

Simple financial markets are greatly enhanced when the availability of<br />

collateral increases, even though there may be diminishing returns in the welfare<br />

created by collateral-based lending. As a minimum, functional markets require that<br />

real property used as security be left in the possession of the borrower, and that<br />

security over movable assets does not hinder their normal commercial use."<br />

Developed financial markets typically operate with a wide range of feasible<br />

collateral assets, and sophisticated financial markets similarly require commensurate<br />

techniques for taking security, for example, in using future receipts and providing for<br />

securitization. Nonetheless, questions and anomalies exist even in advanced<br />

financial markets. De Soto asserts that property must be allowed in use as collateral<br />

in order to encourage economic development, but then fails to distinguish between<br />

the legal and institutional issues concerning property, which he addresses in a<br />

"capitalization process," and in the use of property as collateral, except in relation to<br />

the recording or registration of property rights. In reality, capital is created or<br />

released only given both aspects of the framework supporting the use of property<br />

and property rights as collateral for secured transactions. To refine de Soto's<br />

analysis, property rights must exist and property must also be usable in support of<br />

funding for a financial system to develop comprehensively beyond a basic level."<br />

Despite the importance of collateral and secured transactions, this is an area of<br />

law involving highly varied legal systems, which in developed jurisdictions is also<br />

highly technical. Perhaps as a result, secured transactions tend to receive analytical<br />

attention at relatively advanced levels and involve those emerging economies that<br />

are already well-progressed in systems supporting basic secured transactions. Once<br />

43. An alternative approach distinguishes between the common law view of the firm as a nexus of<br />

contractual bargains, following Ronald H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm, 4 ECONOMICA 386 (1937), and<br />

the more civilian view of the firm as a commercial hub of rights and obligations.<br />

44. Which might be the case, for example, under the traditional English common law mortgage or civil<br />

law possessory pledge.<br />

45. Note that in certain jurisdictions in the study core group, sophisticated financial transactions and<br />

state funding mechanisms exist alongside relatively primitive consumer banking or low-scale credit<br />

creation.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 529 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

such transactions are supported by a legal and institutional system, there is<br />

considerable development potential in enhancing similar support for more advanced<br />

secured transactions. Furthermore, sophisticated transactions may provide an<br />

interim financing solution for states with incomplete or emerging legal systems.<br />

A. Real Property<br />

Recent research supports the view that systems of finance based upon property<br />

are highly relevant to financial and economic development. 46 Byamugisha's 1999<br />

World Bank study develops a theoretical framework to guide the empirical analysis<br />

of the effects of property finance on an entire economy, 47 arguing that the conceptual<br />

framework linking real estate finance to financial development and economic growth<br />

has five main features. First, land tenure security and investment incentives; second,<br />

land title, collateral, and credit; third, land liquidity, deposit mobilization, and<br />

investment; fourth, land markets, transactions, and efficiency; and last, labor<br />

mobility and efficiency. All must be effective to facilitate real estate-based finance,<br />

and each demands the existence of appropriate legal infrastructure.<br />

Given the significance of real estate finance for economic development, an<br />

ensuing question focuses on markets in which the secondary refinancing of mortgage<br />

lending is prominent. For example, a 1997 World Bank study analyzed factors<br />

hindering the development of home loan markets in the transition economies of<br />

Central and Eastern Europe and proposed a strategy to expedite their<br />

development. 48 The analysis shows that banks in transition economies may be<br />

reluctant to make mortgage loans for house purchase because of the scale of risks<br />

they perceive in such lending; that is, the extent of credit, interest rate basis, and<br />

liquidity risks. It suggests that a secondary mortgage market is likely to assist in<br />

solving these problems by allowing banks to manage their loan books to meet<br />

preferences over risk concentration and duration, assuming that the initial primary<br />

provision of loans meets certain institutional standards.<br />

A third World Bank study argues that successful land and real estate reforms<br />

must be "comprehensive in design, even if implementation is phased in over time., 49<br />

It contends that such reforms include three elements: first, institutional reforms that<br />

better define property rights, reduce information asymmetries and improve contract<br />

performance (termed Property Rights, Information, Contracting and Enforcement);<br />

46. In addition to de Soto's suggestion, supra note 31, that legal reform in developing economies can<br />

energize idle capital, North & Thomas, supra note 12, argue that efficient economic organization is the key<br />

to growth; Nathan Rosenberg & L. E. Birdzell, Jr., HOW THE WEST GREW RICH: THE ECONOMIC<br />

TRANSFORMATION OF THE WESTERN WORLD (1986), argue that Western economic development hinged<br />

on factors promoting experimentation; Goldsmith, supra note 25, provides empirical evidence that the<br />

growth of democratic freedoms and property rights in poor countries may lead to increased local<br />

prosperity; Johan Torstensson, Property Rights and Economic Growth: An Empirical Study, 47 KYKLOS<br />

231 (1994), applies empirical analyses of property rights and economic growth to substantiate the findings<br />

of both Rosenberg & Birdzell and North & Thomas.<br />

47. Frank Byamugisha, The Effects of Land Registration on Financial Development and Economic<br />

Growth: A Theoretical and Conceptual Framework (World Bank Pol'y Res. Working Paper No. 2240,<br />

1999).<br />

48. Dwight M. Jaffe & Bertrand Renaud, Strategies to Develop Mortgage Markets in Transition<br />

Economies (World Bank Pol'y Res. Working Paper No. 1697, 1996).<br />

49. Ahmed Galal & Omar Razzaz, Reforming Land and Real Estate Markets 31 (World Bank Policy<br />

Research Working Paper No. 2616, 2001).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 530 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 531<br />

second, capital market reforms making mortgage finance available at reasonable<br />

costs, especially for the poor (Finance and Risk Management); and third, market<br />

reforms that reduce or eliminate distortions in the price of goods and services, the<br />

production of which is enabled by land and real estate assets (Market Regulation<br />

and Fiscal Policy). Their conclusions tie effective mortgage markets to the broader<br />

concept of using real estate finance to encourage all aspects of financial and<br />

economic development.<br />

Jaffee and Renaud suggest that secondary mortgage markets confer two main<br />

benefits: allowing lenders to shed risks associated with holding mortgages, and<br />

creating common standards for credit evaluation and collateral procedures that lead<br />

to greater efficiency in new mortgage lending. They suggest that governments adopt<br />

catalytic policies in developing secondary mortgage market systems and institutions.<br />

This follows the experience of the U.S. and certain other developed countries, and<br />

has been adopted by several of the jurisdictions considered in this article.<br />

B. International Standards for Movables<br />

Wide disparities exist in secured transactions law in developed economies, and<br />

are often central in distinctions between common and civil law traditions. '° As a<br />

result of those disparities, there exist no internationally agreed standards or<br />

principles governing secured transactions." Creating effective provisions for secured<br />

transactions demands a mastery of many aspects of an entire legal system, including<br />

laws of property, obligations, insolvency, and civil procedure, and of administrative<br />

practices and procedures such as registration and enforcement. Nonetheless,<br />

research shows that the sound development of legal infrastructure underlies<br />

functioning collateral-based credit provision and that inadequacies in such<br />

infrastructures hinder financial and economic development.2<br />

Recent guidance from the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) describes<br />

the features of a generic collateral and credit law, 53 which include two main elements.<br />

First are credit laws to govern creditor-debtor relationships in commercial<br />

transactions. These may be established by common law, contract law, civil codes or<br />

specific legislation, for example, in usury laws, banking statutes or creditor-debtor<br />

statutes. Second, are pledges and collateral laws helping to create and enforce rights<br />

in collateral security, preferably through legislation of specific or general application,<br />

rather than through contract or common law. Such laws establish priority rankings<br />

among secured and unsecured claims in situations of default or insolvency, requiring<br />

legislation of a specific or general application.<br />

50. For an excellent discussion, see Fr6d~rique Dahan, Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong> in Western<br />

Advanced Economies: Exposing Myths, in EUROPEAN BANK FOR RECONSTRUCTION AND<br />

DEVELOPMENT, LAW IN TRANSITION 37 (2000), and sources cited therein.<br />

51. See Arjun Goswami & Hamid Sharif, Preface in Nuria de la Pena, Heywood Fleisig & Philip<br />

Wellons, Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong> Reform in Asia: Unleashing the Potential of Collateral. in LAW AND<br />

POLICY REFORM AT THE ASIAN DEVELOPMENT BANK 2 (2000).<br />

52. See generally de la Pena et al., supra note 51.<br />

53. BANK FOR INT'L SETTLEMENTS COMMITFEE ON PAYMENT AND SETTLEMENT SYSTEMS,<br />

GENERAL GUIDANCE FOR NATIONAL PAYMENT SYSTEM DEVELOPMENT 65-5 (2006).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 531 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

Example of such laws and regulations include the U.S. Uniform Commercial<br />

Code (UCC) Article 9; the European Union Directive 20021471EC on financial<br />

collateral arrangements; the 1997 OHADA Uniform <strong>Law</strong> on Security Rights; the<br />

1994 European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) Model <strong>Law</strong> on<br />

Secured Transactions; the UNCITRAL Legislative Guide on Secured Transactions;<br />

the Cape Town Convention on International Interests in Mobile Equipment; and the<br />

West African Economic and Monetary Union Regulation 15I2002ICM/UEMOA<br />

Regarding Payment Systems in the Member <strong>State</strong>s.<br />

Among multilateral agencies, the EBRD's Model <strong>Law</strong> is one of the few<br />

international standards for secured transactions that has been applied successfully as<br />

part of an established process to collateral law reform, drawing also upon the Bank's<br />

core principles and glossary. 5 ' The Asian Development Bank (ADB) has assisted in<br />

creating specific new secured transaction frameworks and the World Bank has<br />

addressed some of these issues in relation to insolvency. More directly, the United<br />

Nations Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong> (UNCITRAL) is completing a<br />

Legislative Guide on Secured Transactions. 5 Other significant international efforts<br />

have been made by the International Institute for the Unification of Private <strong>Law</strong><br />

(UNIDROIT), 6 while regional efforts are under way in North America, 57 Asia, " and<br />

Europe. In addition, important harmonization efforts were made in respect of U.S.<br />

UCC Article 9 and Canada's Personal Property Security Acts, with both frameworks<br />

often serving as models in East Asia and elsewhere.<br />

C. Collateral in East Asia<br />

A sound framework for secured lending can encourage the provision of credit<br />

and assist in the development of domestic financial markets. At the same time, any<br />

system that involves the widespread use of collateral assets to support corporate<br />

lending may risk fostering a monopolistic banking sector. The use of secured lending<br />

as a proxy for informed risk appraisal can become inefficient to the economy as a<br />

whole, both by encouraging wasteful credit risk substitution and acting as a force<br />

oppressive to non-financial trade creditors. In East Asia, an over-reliance by<br />

lenders on the use of private and corporate real estate as collateral for corporate<br />

credit may have contributed to the scale and rapidity of the 1997-98 financial crisis.<br />

Following the widespread collapse of asset values, this over-reliance provoked a<br />

severe subsequent credit squeeze affecting otherwise "healthy" borrowers, even in<br />

national markets that were the least affected by the general loss in confidence.<br />

Collateral must be available as security to release the flow of capital but not so<br />

unreasonably as to protect the oppressive and inefficient.<br />

54. See John Simpson & Joachim Menze, Ten Years of Secured Transactions Reform, in EUROPEAN<br />

BANK FOR RECONSTRUCTION AND DEVELOPMENT, LAW IN TRANSITION 20 (2000).<br />

55. See UNCITRAL, http://www.uncitral.org (last visited Nov. 24, 2006).<br />

56. See UNIDROIT, Convention on International Factoring, May 28, 1988, available at<br />

http://www.unidroit.orglenglish/conventions/1988factoring/main.htm (last visited Nov. 24, 2006);<br />

UNIDROIT Convention on International Interests in Mobile Equipment (2001), available at<br />

http://www.unidroit.org/english/conventions/mobile-equipment/main.htm (last visited Nov. 24, 2006).<br />

57. See American <strong>Law</strong> Institute, International Secured Transactions Project (1997), available at<br />

http://www.ali.org (last visited Nov. 24, 2006).<br />

58. See de la Pena, Fleisig & Wellons, supra note 51.<br />

59. See also supra notes 41 and 42.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 532 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 533<br />

These concerns prompt a series of questions applicable to any jurisdiction.<br />

First, to what extent is commercial secured lending or title finance possible? Second,<br />

what legal provisions exist for home mortgages? Third, what provisions are made<br />

for the transfer of secured claims? Fourth, what are the principal effects of related<br />

legal reforms, for example, in civil jurisdictions that choose to enact wholesale<br />

securitization legislation? Fifth, what is the position of secured claims vis-A-vis<br />

statutory priority, for example, in government or employee creditor claims? Last, is<br />

there simplicity of execution, perfection, notification, registration, and enforcement?<br />

Table 2 synthesizes an analysis of these issues in the economies addressed by this<br />

study, using a rising 1-5 scale. Scores such as 2/3 represent an intermediate appraisal<br />

between two given levels. As with Tables 5, 7, and 8, these "split" scores are<br />

intended to reflect degrees of uncertainty as to commercial outcomes.<br />

TABLE 2: LEGAL FRAMEWORK FOR CREDITOR RIGHTS<br />

Enforcement Security Registration Enforcement<br />

of Unsecured Interest and Disclosure of Secured<br />

Rights Legislation of Secured Rights<br />

Rights<br />

Cambodia 1 160 16 1<br />

China 2 2 2 2<br />

Indonesia 1 2 1/2 1<br />

Malaysia 5 4 4 5<br />

Philippines 2 2/3 2/3 2<br />

South Korea 3 1/2 1/2 2/3<br />

Taiwan 3 4 3 3/4<br />

Thailand 2 1/2 2 2<br />

Vietnam 1 1 1 1<br />

Hong Kong 5 4 4 5<br />

Singapore 5 4 4 5<br />

Here, granting and making security effective is treated as a form of property<br />

right, regardless of the nature of the legal systems under review. Any appraisal will<br />

therefore question how the law links the granting of security to the rights of general<br />

creditors in both normal and distressed circumstances. Table 2 thus shows how the<br />

system now supports, undermines, or confuses all aspects of secured transactions.<br />

No account is taken of informal systems, even if commercially entrenched. 62 Ideally,<br />

the law will allow simple cost-effective creation of security without affecting rights of<br />

60. When enacted, a forthcoming secured transactions law is expected to allow a score of "4" in this<br />

category.<br />

61. When implemented, new provisions are expected to allow a score of "4" in this category.<br />

62. But account is taken of legal provisions peculiar to certain jurisdictions, such as Taiwan's right of<br />

dien which is recognized in the Civil Code Art. 911 as a form of leasehold interest in immovable property,<br />

or the contractual antichresis permitted under the Philippines Civil Code Art. 2132, but which is<br />

increasingly disused as a form of pledge.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 533 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

conventional day-to-day collateral usage. It will be public, transparent, function<br />

without discrimination, and be enforceable in ways compatible with declared public<br />

policy, especially in relation to insolvency, receivership, and rearrangements<br />

following corporate distress.<br />

The effectiveness of a national legal and administrative framework permitting<br />

the creation of collateral for secured transactions is revealed in several elements, not<br />

all of which are consistently present in the review countries. Among the matters to<br />

be considered are the ease and cost of creating reliable security interests, the systems<br />

for such interests to be disclosed, the costs and risks associated with the enforcement<br />

of charges, the relationship of security and collateral with insolvency and<br />

receivership practice, and the operation of creditor protection and stays to<br />

enforcement. These are contained in Table 2.<br />

Civil and common law traditionally have different approaches to security<br />

interests, and the introduction of reform always needs to be sensitive to the existing<br />

contractual and legal setting. While the EBRD Model <strong>Law</strong> on Secured Transactions<br />

was intended to be adopted by jurisdictions of all types, it is likely that the presence<br />

of relatively well-developed legal systems in the core review group make a single<br />

benchmark impractical. Such a device might have value, however, in other<br />

developing Asian jurisdictions. 63 Elsewhere, recent legislative reforms appear to be<br />

effective in supporting transaction creation, but have yet to be tested in cases<br />

involving economic stress, in particular a downward phase in the credit risk cycle or<br />

weakening. This applies to Indonesia, South Korea, and Thailand, for example, as<br />

well as to Cambodia's pending Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong> and the registry that will<br />

support its implementation. In each case, a further concern for the integrity of new<br />

laws in relation to existing and succeeding legislation may arise, given that measures<br />

are often introduced in discrete steps despite leading to a complex commercial<br />

whole. In China, for example, legislation introduced since 2003 has necessitated the<br />

reconsideration of statutes that were created in recent but earlier days of reform.<br />

Likewise, implementation of China's 2007 Property <strong>Law</strong> is likely to have significant<br />

impact, though the exact scope is as yet unclear.<br />

In a related area of law, securitization legislation or decrees have been adopted<br />

in recent years and remain largely untested in Indonesia and the Philippines.' Those<br />

introduced in South Korea, Taiwan, and Thailand appear to be transactionally sound<br />

but have not yet been made subject to credit or valuation stress of the kind indicated<br />

in the preceding paragraph.<br />

1. Overview<br />

Asia's legal provisions for secured credit transactions regimes at the onset of<br />

the 1997-98 financial crisis were at least as outdated and inefficient as its insolvency<br />

laws. Yet less effort has since been made to reform those laws. Immediately after<br />

the crisis, most attention was directed to reforming corporate reorganization<br />

procedures and other features of insolvency law, even though such laws cannot work<br />

63. Vietnam, for example, introduced a general bankruptcy law in 1993 (and a new bankruptcy law in<br />

2004) and commercial and property laws in 1991.<br />

64. A recent unreported decision of the Indonesian Supreme Court may affect the use of a special<br />

purpose vehicle to facilitate foreign currency borrowing by Indonesian entities. See Kate Linebaugh, How<br />

Indonesia's Bond Market Stayed Hot Despite Court Ruling, WALL ST. J. ASIA (Nov. 10, 2006) at A22.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 534 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 535<br />

efficiently when secured creditors find it difficult or impossible to enforce their rights<br />

in bankruptcy. Such delays were common in Asia prior to the financial crisis. 65<br />

Similarly, credit creation is adversely affected when either valid collateral must be<br />

held in possession by a secured creditor or limits exist to the permissible categories<br />

of assets that may be used as collateral. As will be seen in the country-specific<br />

discussion below, these problems were also endemic prior to the crisis, 66 but its<br />

impact finally drew attention to the need for coordinated legal reform as well as the<br />

creation of modern provisions for secured transactions. Thailand is an example of<br />

how this acceptance has been made, as legislation was under preparation<br />

immediately prior to the suspension of the legislature in September 2006.<br />

2. Real Property<br />

In each jurisdiction within this study, the legal system provides for real property<br />

to be offered and taken as collateral. However, there is considerable divergence as<br />

how best to resolve a variety of issues, including the following: the ease and<br />

efficiency with which mortgages, charges or liens may be created; the requirements<br />

for registration and its usefulness to third parties; whether a mortgagor retains title<br />

to collateral while the extension of credit that the charge purports to secure remains<br />

outstanding; and how secured creditors may enforce their collateral rights.<br />

Differences also exist in some cases in the treatment of collateral arising from<br />

varying statutory provisions for real property ownership by domestic and foreign<br />

interests.<br />

Table 3 does not address the distribution of property rights, which is a focus of<br />

de Soto's work that merits further attention in the context of the relationship<br />

between state governance and property rights, and economic outcomes.<br />

TABLE 3: TREATMENT OF REAL PROPERTY<br />

Cambodia<br />

China 67<br />

Real property may be mortgaged, but enforcement can be<br />

extremely problematic. Registration is efficient and effective. A<br />

foreign creditor may take a mortgage over land but not become<br />

the owner of land.<br />

Land may not be mortgaged, but mortgages over land-use rights<br />

are permitted. Registration is necessary to protect secured<br />

creditor rights. The enforcement of a mortgage can require<br />

litigation in cases in which the mortgagee and mortgagor cannot<br />

reach agreement as to how the mortgagee claim may be<br />

satisfied. Transactions involving mortgages to be held by<br />

foreign entities are subject to prior approval and registration<br />

with the <strong>State</strong> Administration of Foreign Exchange (SAFE).<br />

65. See ADB Office of the General Counsel, Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> Reforms in the Asian and Pacific Region,<br />

Report of the Office of the General Counsel on TA 5795-Reg: Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> Reforms, <strong>Law</strong> and Policy<br />

Reform at the ADB 10-11, 70-75 (2000) [hereinafter Report on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> Reforms].<br />

66. See Lampros Vassiliou, The Restructuring Revolution in the Asia-Pacific Region, in THE ASIA-<br />

PACIFIC RESTRUCTURING AND INSOLVENCY GUIDE 2006 18,21 (2006).<br />

67. After extensive discussions and the withdrawal of an earlier draft law in 2006, a new property<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 535 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

Indonesia<br />

Philippines<br />

Security interests may be taken in land, but it often proves<br />

difficult for creditors to enforce a security interest. The process<br />

is inefficient; enforcement can take many years. Auction fees<br />

and taxes are high and, in practice, recourse to the courts is<br />

almost always necessary." Official registers are maintained<br />

manually, which causes difficulties for potential lenders wishing<br />

to search for title or prior claims. 69 Security rights may be<br />

impaired by the creation of a parent company guaranty in<br />

respect of like debt.<br />

Real property may be mortgaged (under provisions of the Civil<br />

Code). While both registration and notarization are necessary<br />

for creditor protection, the requirements are set out in a mix of<br />

statute and presidential decree. Ownership is retained by the<br />

mortgagor while a charge is outstanding. Delays in foreclosure<br />

can occur because the secured party must use the courts in the<br />

absence of any contractual agreement for extrajudicial<br />

foreclosure." Contractual antichresis was a common form of<br />

commercial pledge, but it is becoming increasingly less used.<br />

Unless stated by agreement, mortgages over land will embrace<br />

subsequent buildings or improvements to the land, and may<br />

gain inadvertent priority over other subsequent charges.<br />

Foreign creditors may become mortgagees of land but not<br />

buildings, and may subsequently not take possession of land.<br />

rights law was approved by the 10th National People's Congress in March 2007, to take effect on October<br />

1, 2007. See Property Rights <strong>Law</strong> of the People's Republic of China 2007. This covers both real property<br />

and movable assets, and for the first time establishes rights in respect of both state and non-state interests.<br />

The law makes most real property ownership rights contingent upon registration. See id. Art. 9-22. Art.<br />

170-240 establish conditions for the granting of security interests by a property owner, including the right to<br />

mortgage real property and specified movable assets, and the right to pledge other assets, including certain<br />

defined intangibles. The creation of registry facilities throughout China will be a considerable<br />

administrative burden.<br />

68. EMIR NURMANSYAH, THEODOOR BAKKER, CLIFFORD REES & DAVID ADAMS, INDONESIA: THE<br />

ASIA PACIFIC RESTRUCTURING AND INSOLVENCY GUIDE 80 (2006).<br />

69. Id.<br />

70. RICARDO ONGKIKO, CARINA LAFORTEZA, CARLOS FRANCISO & COSETrE CANILAO,<br />

PHILIPPINES: THE ASIA PACIFIC RESTRUCTURING AND INSOLVENCY GUIDE 135 (2006), noting that<br />

mortgage contracts now usually provide for extra-judicial foreclosure to address this problem.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 536 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 537<br />

South Korea<br />

Taiwan<br />

Thailand<br />

Vietnam<br />

Most real estate rights must be registered. However, there are<br />

important exceptions from this rule (e.g., property acquired<br />

through inheritance or pursuant to a judgment auction).<br />

The Civil Code allows mortgages to be created over defined<br />

classes of real property, 7 and for possessory security or<br />

attachments. In addition, the right of "dien" is allowed as a<br />

form of possessory pledge similar to a leasehold interest, and<br />

may be created effectively over assets not specified in law.<br />

Registration in all cases is mandatory and efficient, without<br />

which the charge will be void. There is some uncertainty as to<br />

whether notice or consent is required of a secured creditor for<br />

the creation of a subsequent mortgage. Foreign creditors are<br />

restricted as to the types of real property over which they may<br />

hold security interests.<br />

Real property may be mortgaged and registration is necessary<br />

to protect the secured creditor's rights, but foreclosure cannot<br />

occur unless loan interest or charges have been outstanding for<br />

five years, contributing to an inefficient enforcement process<br />

that can extend over many years. Separate charges are<br />

necessary in respect of plant or equipment contained in a<br />

mortgaged property, and may be subject to official inspection.<br />

The 1992 constitution adopted the general recognition of<br />

private property rights but land ownership continues to be<br />

vested solely in the state. Nonetheless, rights of land use are<br />

clear and may be mortgaged under the Land <strong>Law</strong> of 1993.<br />

Hong Kong, All allow for a charge to be taken over land, which must be<br />

Malaysia, registered. 72 Hong Kong and Singapore also provide for<br />

Singapore mortgages to be taken over land, but in Hong Kong (since 1984)<br />

the mortgage may be created only by a legal charge. The<br />

Malaysian courts will generally recognize a charge that is<br />

executed but not yet registered. All three jurisdictions allow for<br />

the appointment of a receiver to protect the creditor's interest<br />

and in all three jurisdictions there is a high level of predictability<br />

and efficiency as to the creditor's ability to enforce its rights.<br />

Hong Kong land ownership is (with a single exception) held by<br />

the territory's government but this does not materially affect<br />

rights of use or the creation of security.<br />

71. It was until recently customary for lenders to require registration of a "comprehensive mortgage"<br />

over an undefined amount prior to approving a loan (compared to the widespread practice elsewhere<br />

making disbursal subject to security conditions) but the practice was held invalid by the courts as being<br />

contrary to the specificity required of charges by the Civil Code. Reform has not yet been completed.<br />

72. <strong>Law</strong>s governing land registration differ between Peninsular and East Malaysia, the latter<br />

excluding Labuan, which became a federal territory in 1990 upon being designated an offshore financial<br />

center. The taking of land and movable assets owned by Labuan companies as collateral is governed<br />

largely by the Offshore Companies Act 1990.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 537 2006-2007


538 TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL VOL. 42:515<br />

3. Movables and Unsecured Property<br />

The treatment of secured rights over movable property is still more varied<br />

throughout the study group. Although none of the jurisdictions within this study has<br />

adopted a U.S. Article 9-style regime, the English origin systems of Hong Kong,<br />

Malaysia and Singapore work relatively well. However, Table 4 shows that delays<br />

and inefficiencies in the enforcement of secured rights are common. Similarly, limits<br />

to the movable assets that may be used as collateral is problematic or constraining in<br />

most jurisdictions. These include bars to taking security interests in chattel paper or<br />

accounts receivable, and more broadly a lack of provisions for charges over future<br />

property or the use of security to collateralize future loans.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 538 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 539<br />

TABLE 4: TREATMENT OF MOVABLES<br />

Cambodia<br />

A new Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong> is expected to be enacted in<br />

the foreseeable future, providing a modern legal framework for<br />

security, including support through an electronic registration<br />

system. However, enforcement is likely to remain problematic,<br />

and the commercial effectiveness of the law may be colored by<br />

other current omissions in law.<br />

China 73 Mortgages may be taken over existing tangible movable<br />

property, but not over future property. Secured creditors must<br />

register their claims to protect all such non-possessory rights.<br />

They may also protect themselves through possession in the<br />

form of a pledge. As with real property, foreign entities seeking<br />

security over movable property must comply with SAFE<br />

approval and registration procedures. The treatment of security<br />

interests in intangible assets such as bank accounts or<br />

receivables is less straightforward. Regulations have been<br />

issued allowing mortgages over such assets, but the<br />

effectiveness of these new forms of collateral is largely untested.<br />

Enforcement of unsecured claims can sometimes run into<br />

resistance at a local level; there have been reported instances in<br />

which banks and their clients have colluded to hide assets from<br />

the court.<br />

Indonesia<br />

Philippines<br />

Under the Fiduciary Security <strong>Law</strong>, a debtor may transfer title in<br />

goods to a creditor and retain possession of the goods in the<br />

absence of any default. Pledges are also permitted. A fiduciary<br />

assignment may be taken for security purposes over intangible<br />

property and receivables. 4 As with real property, enforcement<br />

over movable property requires recourse to the courts, and both<br />

auction fees and taxes are punitive. 7 " In essence, secured<br />

creditors foreclosing on collateral are forced to resort to<br />

substantially the same court proceedings as unsecured<br />

creditors. 76<br />

Chattel mortgages and pledges are permitted over movable<br />

property. Chattel mortgages must be recorded. Philippine law<br />

does not recognize chattel mortgages over future property; but<br />

the courts have created exceptions for interests in inventories of<br />

raw materials, goods in process, and finished goods. Future<br />

obligations cannot be secured by chattel mortgages.<br />

73. The treatment of movables will be clarified by the introduction of the new Property Rights <strong>Law</strong> of<br />

the People's Republic of China 2007, to come into force in October 2007. See supra note 67, providing at<br />

Arts. 179-202 for the creation of mortgages over specified movable assets. Such mortgages will take effect<br />

only upon registration.<br />

74. NURMANSYAH ET AL., supra note 68, at 80.<br />

75. Id.<br />

76. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 539 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

South Korea Rights in personal property may only be protected by<br />

possession. South Korean law does not recognize purchase<br />

money security interests or floating liens.<br />

Taiwan<br />

Thailand<br />

Vietnam<br />

Hong Kong<br />

Malaysia<br />

Singapore<br />

Non-possessory charges are possible under the Chattel Secured<br />

Transaction Act and by separate laws regarding ships and<br />

aircraft. Registration is mandatory in each case in order to<br />

protect priority. Enforcement is generally procedural and not<br />

subject to judicial uncertainty.<br />

Only certain forms of movable property may be mortgaged,<br />

including large ships, boats, floating houses, beasts of burden,<br />

and classes of machinery. Creditors holding rights of retention<br />

are also recognized as secured creditors. Other types of<br />

property may be pledged. Enforcement of secured rights<br />

requires either a court judgment or a public auction.<br />

Enforcement is slow and costly. Fixed and floating charges are<br />

not permitted at present, but would be allowed under draft<br />

secured transactions law. The enforcement of unsecured debts<br />

in Thailand can extend for many years.<br />

Private property rights are constitutionally recognized and<br />

charges over movables permitted by the civil code.<br />

Improvements were made to Vietnam's secured transaction<br />

framework in 2005 amendments to the civil code, which took<br />

effect in January 2006. Further decrees are expected to assist<br />

with the implementation of these changes. A National<br />

Registration Agency for Secured Transactions has been<br />

established with offices in Hanoi, Ho Chi Minh City, and<br />

Danang. However, enforcement of security interests remains<br />

difficult. Unless bankruptcy proceedings have been<br />

commenced, a court order is not necessary for the enforcement<br />

of a secured transaction.<br />

The laws in all three jurisdictions provide a variety of security<br />

over movable property (both tangible and intangible), including<br />

charges, liens, and pledges. Retention of title is also permitted.<br />

Security may be taken over future property. Fixed charges may<br />

be taken over tangible assets and floating charges may be taken<br />

over classes of variable assets such as inventory or book debts.<br />

The taking of fixed charges over book debts by secured<br />

creditors is much more difficult..7 These English-origin systems<br />

require the registration of many types of charges, including<br />

charges over book debts and floating charges over the general<br />

undertaking of a company, but statutory rules are less clear and<br />

comprehensive than U.S. UCC Article 9. Usual practice in<br />

77. In these three jurisdictions the decision by the U.K. House of Lords limiting the validity of fixed<br />

charges over book debts to cases in which the secured creditor exercises sufficient control over the<br />

collateral (e.g., through including a provision in the debenture requiring the deposit of proceeds of book<br />

debts into a blocked account and in fact operating the account as a blocked account) would be persuasive<br />

authority. See Re Spectrum Plus Ltd; National Westminster Bank plc v. Spectrum Plus Ltd. and others<br />

[2005] 2 BCLC 269.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 540 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 541<br />

these three jurisdictions is for a debenture to provide a secured<br />

financial creditor with contractual remedies upon default,<br />

allowing appointment of a receiver or special manager. All<br />

have efficient debt collection procedures for unsecured<br />

creditors.<br />

D. Securitization<br />

Securitized transactions require a permissive framework of existing or<br />

dedicated law, acceptance of certain accounting principles, acceptable regulatory<br />

assent, and a non-discriminatory taxation background. 78 They also require accepted<br />

commercial precepts that are not matters of legal policy; for example, a lack of<br />

contractual restrictions to the transfer of financial claims. Such restrictions are<br />

common in all review markets, except in Hong Kong and Singapore.<br />

The details of typical transactions will vary among jurisdictions, but are<br />

assumed to entail the irrevocable transfer of assets to an insubstantive special<br />

purpose vehicle (SPV) to which the asset seller has no ties of ownership or control.<br />

Funding for the asset purchase is provided by the sale of public or private securities<br />

to third party investors. The transaction must withstand any legal claim in<br />

bankruptcy against the asset seller; its economics must withstand taxes and duties on<br />

transfer; in most cases, securities issued by the SPV must provide for the dependable<br />

subordination of claims.<br />

In general, the elements of law typically associated with securitized transactions<br />

in advanced markets are present in the three common law review jurisdictions,<br />

especially those affecting existing or future claims originated by financial<br />

intermediaries. However, certain future claims that cannot be specified in ways<br />

required by current law may be seen as hazardous source material by investors or<br />

third party monoline insurers, such as credit card receivables.<br />

A summary of the provisions for securitized transactions and their effectiveness<br />

is given in Table 5. Its assessments of the effectiveness of enabling legal provisions<br />

(column 2), the enforcement of foreclosure or repossession of source assets (column<br />

5), and ongoing threats to the integrity of transfer of assets to a SPV (column 6) are<br />

in each case based on transactional evidence and appraisals of governing laws.<br />

However, it must be noted that in most jurisdictions, transactional integrity has yet<br />

to be fully tested through a complete credit cycle. This would apply in relation to<br />

new rules such as the creation of real estate investment trusts in common law<br />

jurisdictions such as Hong Kong and Singapore. Nevertheless, in each case the<br />

probability is small that a completed transaction will be successfully challenged.<br />

While aspects of law may now be clear in some cases, it may be little used, such<br />

as law regarding private contracts in the Philippines or Thailand, and is thus yet<br />

untested. Further, no significant number of completed securitized transactions has<br />

yet to undergo periods of economic stress or be attacked by creditors of the<br />

originator. In contrast, since 1998, South Korean reforms seem to be demonstrably<br />

successful.<br />

78. See Douglas Arner, Emerging Market Economies and Government Promotion of Securitization, 12<br />

DUKE J. COMP. & INT'L L. 505 (2002).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 541 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

Malaysian common law supports securitization. Rules setting out general<br />

parameters for securitization were first published only in 2001, but sales of whole or<br />

partial interests in pools of home mortgages began in the mid-1980s. Shariahcompliant<br />

transactions have been few to date and involve intricate structuring at all<br />

stages, but are now considered to be generally feasible, at least as single deals.<br />

TABLE 5: PROVISIONS FOR SECURITIZATION<br />

Sale, assignment, or other conveyance of Creation,<br />

assets by originators to securitization maintenance, Other<br />

vehicles<br />

and operation of<br />

SPV<br />

-t CD o:.<br />

. CD -CD pc CD<br />

-.o.---R. ' O"<br />

=o C -0 C0CD<br />

=<br />

. C, t a. -.<br />

- 't- t<br />

-. 0- .-.<br />

Uq CD AC -t<br />

Cn Cn 0<br />

-- _-. <<br />

"a t .3 (D W CD o<br />

0 CD<br />

Cambodia NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

China 1/2 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Indonesia 2 2 2 2 1 2 2<br />

Malaysia 5 4 4 3/4 4 4 5<br />

Philippines 2/3 2/3 1/2 2/3 2/3 1/2 2/3<br />

South<br />

Korea<br />

Taiwan 4/5 4 3/4 4 4 2/3 4<br />

Thailand 3/4 3 3/4 3/4 2/3 4/5 2/3<br />

Vietnam NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

Hong 54 5<br />

Kong<br />

Singapore 5 5 5 4 5 5 5<br />

Since 1998, four of the eight civil law review jurisdictions have introduced, or<br />

are planning to introduce, enabling laws that permit the creation of securitized<br />

transactions recognizable by international standards. The most notable provisions<br />

are shown in Table 6. In particular, these allow for the creation of SPVs, which<br />

would not otherwise be permitted by the general provisions of national civil codes. 9<br />

79. A recent unreported decision of the Indonesian Supreme Court has created transaction<br />

uncertainty in the context of foreign borrowing by affirming the contiguous treatment of a company<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 542 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 543<br />

Indonesia permits certain transactions under authority granted to the principal<br />

securities regulator, Bapepam. Several Indonesian securitized transactions were<br />

completed before 1997 but post-crisis deals are virtually non-existent because<br />

counterparties may have been more willing to enter deals in a time of moderate<br />

confidence than thereafter. Since 2000, there has been some doubt that regulatory<br />

decrees, upon which any new transaction will depend, may subsist during its lifetime.<br />

Finally, certain jurisdictions are affected by related issues of law, tax, or market<br />

rules, rather than pure securitization provisions. This increases contractual<br />

uncertainty, and applies, for example, in the Philippines and for domestic<br />

transactions in Taiwan.<br />

TABLE 6: STATUS OF ENABLING LEGISLATION FOR SECURITIZATION °<br />

Cambodia<br />

China<br />

Indonesia<br />

Philippines<br />

South Korea<br />

Taiwan<br />

Thailand<br />

Vietnam<br />

Years of Enactment or Proclamation<br />

None<br />

Major bank and possibly other sector securitization legislation<br />

forthcoming 2007-08<br />

Trial deals permitted by banking and securities regulators in<br />

2006-07<br />

Pre-1997 Securitization Decrees<br />

2002-03 Securities Regulator Guidelines<br />

2003 Special Purpose Vehicle Act<br />

2004 Securitization Act (largely untested)<br />

Implementing Rules and Regulations (2005) over credit rating<br />

requirements and the use of SPVs.<br />

1998 Asset-backed Securities <strong>Law</strong><br />

1999 Mortgage-backed Securities <strong>Law</strong><br />

2003 Korea Housing Finance Corporation law<br />

2002 Financial Asset Securitization Act<br />

2003 Real Estate Securitization Act<br />

1997 Securitization Decree<br />

2003 Asset-backed Securitization Act<br />

2004 Special Purpose Vehicle Act<br />

None<br />

guarantor and its subsidiary SPV and voiding a financing contract to which the two entities purported to be<br />

separate parties. This may increase the legal risks of securitized transactions. See also supra note 64.<br />

80. A model for other Asian civil law jurisdictions may have been legislation enabling securitization in<br />

Japan, including notably its 1998 Perfection <strong>Law</strong>, 1998/2000 Asset Liquidation <strong>Law</strong>, and 2004 Trust<br />

Business <strong>Law</strong> (Amendment).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 543 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

V. CREDITOR RIGHTS AND INSOLVENCY<br />

At the formative stage of economic development, the risk and incidence of<br />

defaults by debtors often prevent the efficient deployment of funds for investment.<br />

A proper framework of law that provides both for company incorporation and the<br />

orderly resolution of proceedings for recovery and insolvency is therefore a crucial<br />

foundation of development.<br />

A. Insolvency<br />

A functioning legal framework for insolvency management is essential in the<br />

operation of any modern market-based economy. No commercial sector can function<br />

effectively without mechanisms to recognize and govern the exit of insolvent<br />

participants. Furthermore, the financial sector will limit credit creation for many<br />

companies and individuals if lenders are uncertain that their status as secured<br />

creditors will prevail upon the liquidation of their debtors, or that a reliable means<br />

will be available for the enforcement of properly-constituted security. The general<br />

objectives of a system of corporate insolvency have been described as the reduction<br />

of uncertainty, promotion of efficiency, and fair and equitable treatment for all<br />

participants.' A functioning insolvency regime can thus help reduce and simplify the<br />

risks associated with lending and the potential cost of debt service; if this is the case,<br />

long-run credit availability and capital investment will increase."<br />

Functioning insolvency procedures are thus central to the legal and institutional<br />

environment for sound finance in any market-based economy, regardless of whether<br />

public policy requires the law to favor debtors or creditors. A well-administered<br />

insolvency system may be valuable in promoting market discipline. Effective<br />

insolvency laws provide the means for the identification of non-competitive<br />

participants and, in some cases, for their controlled exit. It thus provides an effective<br />

penalty for the least competitive as well as a potential solution to the ensuing<br />

reallocation of resources. While this view stresses the retroactive character of<br />

insolvency law, it also has a considerable preventive element by creating incentives<br />

for the uncompetitive to improve performance and to avoid the sanction of<br />

administration by a third party on its creditor's behalf.<br />

A number of international organizations and associations have assisted the<br />

development of standards for modern insolvency law and related systems. Many of<br />

these activities have focused in particular on norms and standards for cross-border<br />

insolvency cases, such as the UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong> on Cross-Border Insolvency<br />

and the EU Insolvency Regulation of 2000.83 A working group chaired by the legal<br />

department of the IMF presented a document containing detailed principles for the<br />

development of workable, modern insolvency legislation. 8 While there is no<br />

81. See Report of the G-10, Report of the Contact Group on the Legal and Institutional<br />

Underpinnings of the International Financial System (Sep. 2002), available at<br />

http://www.bis.org/dcms/fd.jsp?p=l&uri=/publ/gten06.htm (last visited Nov. 24, 2006).<br />

82. IMF Legal Department, Orderly & Effective Insolvency Procedures: Key Issues (1999), available<br />

at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2000/03/hagan.htm (last visited Nov. 24, 2006). Note that this<br />

argument is silent as to the quality of investments so financed.<br />

83. UNCITRAL MODEL LAW ON CROSS BORDER INSOLVENCY WITH GUIDE TO ENACTMENT<br />

(1997); Council Regulation 1346/2000 O.J. (L 160).<br />

84. IMF Legal Department, supra note 82.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 544 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 545<br />

internationally agreed key standard in the area of insolvency, the World Bank is<br />

coordinating efforts to develop such a benchmark and is working with UNCITRAL<br />

to develop a suitable framework for its implementation.<br />

The World Bank first issued its Principles and Guidelines for Effective<br />

Insolvency and Creditor Rights Systems in April 2001" and a revised version under<br />

development will take into account feedback from insolvency assessments conducted<br />

under the IMF-World Bank Reports on Observance of Standards and Codes<br />

(ROSC) initiative. 6 The Bank is also preparing a technical report containing<br />

detailed implementation guidelines to support the principles. UNCITRAL released<br />

a Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> in 2005, a combination of model provisions,<br />

recommendations, and explanatory notes that builds upon the work of other<br />

international organizations, including the World Bank, IMF, and ADB. 7<br />

The World Bank identifies nine objectives for effective corporate insolvency:s<br />

1) Integrate with broader national legal and commercial systems.<br />

2) Maximize the value of a firm's assets by providing an option to<br />

reorganize.<br />

3) Strike a careful balance between liquidation and reorganization.<br />

4) Provide for equitable treatment of similarly situated creditors, including<br />

foreign and domestic creditors.<br />

5) Provide for timely, efficient, and impartial resolution of insolvencies.<br />

6) Prevent the premature dismemberment of a debtor's assets by<br />

individual creditors seeking quick judgments.<br />

7) Provide a transparent procedure that contains incentives for gathering<br />

and dispensing information.<br />

85. World Bank, Principles and Guidelines for Effective Insolvency & Creditor Rights Systems (Apr.<br />

2001), available at<br />

http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE[EXTERNAL/TOPICS/LAWANDJUSTICE/GlLD/0,,CONTENTMD<br />

K:20086184-menuPK:146153 -pagePK:64065425-piPK:162156-thesitePK:215006,00.html. The Principles<br />

(ICRPs) were prepared in collaboration with the AfDB, ADB, EBRD, IADB, IFC, IMF, OECD,<br />

UNCITRAL, INSOL International, and International Bar Association.<br />

86. The latest draft dates from 2005. See http://www.worldbank.org/ifa/rose-icr.htm (last visited Nov.<br />

24. 2006).<br />

87. See Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, UNCITRAL, available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/insolven/05-80722-Ebook.pdf (last visited Nov. 24, 2006).<br />

88. World Bank ICRP 6, 24, (Apr. 2001) (stating that these elements were identified by the G-22). Id.<br />

at 24, n.10 (citing G-22 16, 44-45 (1998)).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 545 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

8) Recognize existing creditor rights and respect the priority of claims with<br />

a predictable and established process.<br />

9) Establish a framework for cross-border insolvencies, with recognition of<br />

foreign proceedings.<br />

In supporting these objectives, the thirty-five World Bank insolvency principles<br />

cover five main areas: first, a legal framework for creditor rights (principles 1-5); 89<br />

second, a legal framework for corporate insolvency (principles 6-16); third, corporate<br />

rehabilitation (principles 17-24); four, informal workouts and restructuring<br />

(principles 25-26); and five, institutional and regulatory frameworks for<br />

implementation of the insolvency system (principles 27-35).<br />

The most recent version of the UNCITRAL Guide has two parts. 90 The first<br />

deals with the design of the key objectives and structure of an insolvency law, while<br />

Part II includes core insolvency law provisions. Regretfully, until the revised World<br />

Bank principles and final UNCITRAL Guide are integrated, approved, and<br />

released, it is impossible to identify an international consensus in this area.<br />

B. Interaction between Creditor Rights and Insolvency<br />

Debtor-creditor laws include systems for collecting debts and insolvency<br />

systems for terminating the collection of unpaid debts. Collection systems include:<br />

secured transactions, using movable property as collateral; mortgages, using fixed<br />

property as collateral; and unsecured lending, a system that employs no property or<br />

other rights as collateral. 9 ' One view of the interaction between secured lending and<br />

insolvency law sees each as addressing distinct problems, with separate solutions. A<br />

secured lending system determines how lenders are repaid, whereas an insolvency<br />

system establishes the appropriate treatment for defaulting borrowers.<br />

At the same time, there are important points of intersection between secured<br />

transactions and insolvency, and the two systems must be integrated. Neither system<br />

can substitute for the other. Thus, reforms of debtor-creditor laws must embrace<br />

both secured lending and insolvency law, as well as other closely related areas of law.<br />

The need for such drafting integration may be more widely realized in East Asia<br />

now, as governments contemplate reform, than would have been the case prior to<br />

the 1997-98 financial crisis.<br />

Secured transactions have often been seen as important in improving general<br />

welfare by helping create and encourage certain benefits for society as a whole.<br />

Regardless of the nature of preferred insolvency laws, East Asian national<br />

economies are likely to advance by improving their respective laws on secured<br />

lending. This relies on the premise that general access to credit, and the specific<br />

terms on which it becomes available, will improve in the borrower's favor as the<br />

89. This Section, while at first glance appearing to address collateral and secured transactions,<br />

addresses these only in the context of insolvency.<br />

90. UNCITRAL, Draft Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong>, AICN.9/WG.V/WP.70 (Parts I and II)<br />

(2003).<br />

91. Banking practice in civil law jurisdictions often treats guarantees as providing security, which is<br />

not usual in common law systems, regardless of the effect on credit risk.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 546 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 547<br />

quality of collateral-taking improves. 92 Effective secured transactions systems that<br />

allow for movable property to be used as collateral may allow distressed firms to<br />

gain access to credit and so avoid the final resort of insolvency. In such conditions,<br />

creditors may anticipate repayment without necessarily initiating the insolvency<br />

process.<br />

All security interests must be properly publicized. An effective method of<br />

publication puts both existing and potential creditors on notice that a debtor<br />

company has fewer unencumbered assets available in which potential lenders might<br />

obtain meaningful interests. It also provides notice as to the order of priority for the<br />

distribution of assets if a company becomes insolvent. Filing or registration systems<br />

are comparatively more effective than inefficient systems that rely on possession as a<br />

form of security. The efficient enforcement of security interests is central to an<br />

effective secured transactions system. It also promotes both informal and judicially<br />

supervised workouts. An efficient system will minimize the need for judicial<br />

assistance wherever possible and expedite the enforcement process.<br />

In the interaction between secured transactions and insolvency, the essential<br />

need is for insolvency law to respect the pre-existing priority rights of secured<br />

creditors. If the law poses unreasonable threats to secured lending, banks might<br />

increase transaction charges or restrict access to credit. In addition, when a company<br />

contemplating insolvency charges or mortgages assets to a creditor in exchange for<br />

identifiable value to the company, then as a general rule such charges or mortgages<br />

should not be voided by subsequent insolvency proceedings. Secured creditors<br />

should also be permitted to convert unsecured debts into secured debts, providing<br />

such transactions are completed substantially before the commencement of any<br />

insolvency proceedings. The law should provide that fraudulent or commercially<br />

unfair transactions that have a security component may be avoided. As a general<br />

rule, pre-petition interests should continue in post-petition proceeds, while postpetition<br />

grants of security should be permitted. Last, as a general rule, priorities in<br />

insolvency should be abolished.<br />

Overall, East Asian economies would benefit from enacting insolvency laws<br />

that respect the pre-existing rights of secured creditors. However, in deciding to<br />

what extent exceptions may be permitted and how best to balance the needs of<br />

secured transactions and insolvency, law-makers in East Asia must first determine<br />

which approach they believe most appropriate.<br />

C. Creditor Rights and Insolvency in East Asia<br />

The appraisals given in Table 7 acknowledge extra-legal regulatory guidance<br />

for collaborative multi-creditor practice, for example in Hong Kong, Indonesia,<br />

Malaysia and Thailand. Regulators in these jurisdictions have attempted to instill<br />

informal out-of-court corporate workout practices similar to the well-established<br />

"London Rules," or "London Approach," promoted in the 1970s by the Bank of<br />

England as an alternative to formal court-based corporate insolvency proceedings<br />

92. This is not universally accepted. For an example, see Schwartz, Security Interests, supra note 41,<br />

and Schwartz, Puzzle of Secured Debt, supra note 41 (questioning the economic efficiency of secured<br />

lending).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 547 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

involving multiple financial creditors. 9 After the onset of the Asian financial crisis,<br />

such out-of-court workout procedures were applied more frequently than courtbased<br />

formal reorganizations, although the results were not consistent in all<br />

jurisdictions. 9 4 Most jurisdictions also set up public administrative agencies to assist<br />

with the restructuring of domestic financial intermediaries and the disposal of nonperforming<br />

loans (NPLs).<br />

In both Hong Kong and Singapore, systems and practice are well-established<br />

and generally sophisticated, but legislative reform has tended to lag both market<br />

practice and the willingness of the courts to intervene creatively in cases of corporate<br />

distress.<br />

TABLE 7: DEVELOPMENT OF EFFECTIVE INSOLVENCY SYSTEMS<br />

Legal Corporate Effective<br />

framework orcroae insolvency Coporat decision- making and in isolvency<br />

for corporate implementation mkn n rciinr<br />

insolvency enforcement practitioners<br />

Cambodia NA NA 1 1<br />

China 95 2/3 1 1 1/2<br />

Indonesia 2/3 1 1 1/2<br />

Malaysia 4 4 4 4<br />

Philippines 2/3 2/3 2 2/3<br />

South Korea 4 3/4 3 3/4<br />

Taiwan 3 3 3 3<br />

Thailand 3 2/3 2/3 2/3<br />

Vietnam 1/2 1/2 1 1<br />

Hong Kong 4 5 5 5<br />

Singapore 4/5 5 5 5<br />

1. Insolvency: Pre-1997 Overview<br />

Among the jurisdictions in this study, only Singapore had an insolvency regime<br />

adequate to deal with a high number of corporate failures at the opening of the<br />

Asian financial crisis. All other jurisdictions were hampered by antiquated or<br />

inadequate laws and procedures, many of which dated from colonial times. None<br />

maintained an effective formal corporate rescue procedure. Hong Kong and<br />

Malaysian corporate insolvency procedures were modeled on mid-20th century<br />

English law. Thai law dating from 1940 was influenced by English personal<br />

93. Their precept is that financial creditors act in concert rather than any single creditor competitively<br />

advancing its position in ways that might provoke premature liquidation.<br />

94. See supra note 65 and accompanying text. Informal practice has tended to be successful where the<br />

courts have stood ready to support a consensus reached among creditors and debtors, and where debtors<br />

or their controlling owners have been unable to challenge the enforcement of foreign judgments.<br />

95. In regards to the recently enacted bankruptcy law that came into operation on June 1, 2007.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 548 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 549<br />

bankruptcy laws, while Indonesian law was mainly Dutch in origin and dated from<br />

the late 19th century. South Korea's insolvency regime drew on Japanese law, which<br />

derived from German, Austrian, and U.S. principles and statutes. Taiwan's laws<br />

were also derived from Japan's laws and later, to a lesser extent from U.S. law, with<br />

the last pre-1997 amendments dating from the early 1980s. China's insolvency laws<br />

were written more recently, with bankruptcy provisions for state-owned enterprises<br />

(SOEs) enacted in 1986, and provisions for non-SOE enterprises with legal person<br />

status, in 1991. Vietnam's laws dated from 1994. These regimes used liquidationbased<br />

procedures, with the exception of Singapore. Cambodia still lacks an<br />

insolvency framework. For the most part, these insolvency laws were under-utilized.<br />

Insolvency law in Hong Kong, Malaysia, and Singapore share the same basic<br />

structure of detailed liquidation or winding-up procedures and an abbreviated<br />

scheme of arrangement procedure for use in corporate rescue. The liquidation<br />

procedures in these jurisdictions are still the region's most efficient, although in<br />

need of modernization, but the scheme of arrangement procedure is cumbersome<br />

and expensive. Hong Kong and Malaysian procedures do not provide for an<br />

automatic stay on creditor claims in the absence of a winding-up order; Singapore<br />

operates a stay only on unsecured creditors. In none of these three jurisdictions are<br />

there mechanisms to force uncooperative secured creditors to the bargaining table.<br />

The result is that prior the Asian financial crisis, the procedure was rarely employed,<br />

although it saw more use in Singapore than in Hong Kong and Malaysia.. Singapore<br />

also introduced judicial management procedures in 1987. These procedures may be<br />

initiated either by a debtor company or its creditors, and the procedure provides for<br />

an automatic stay while a judicial manager assumes the responsibility for running the<br />

company and proposing a plan of reorganization for creditor approval."<br />

The evolution of South Korea's insolvency regime has been more complicated.<br />

Until recently, the law had three parts, all dating from 1962, which concerned<br />

bankruptcy, composition, and reorganization. Rather than develop an insolvency<br />

solution, South Korea translated and enacted Japanese laws, so that the Bankruptcy<br />

Act was based on the Japanese Bankruptcy Act 1922, itself derived from German<br />

law. The Composition Act was based on a Japanese composition law taken from<br />

Austrian law; the Reorganization Act copied the Japanese Reorganization Act 1952,<br />

derived in turn from the U.S. Bankruptcy Act 1898. The composition law was<br />

triggered by a debtor's filing and only provided for temporary relief until creditors<br />

voted on a composition plan. The more complicated reorganization process was<br />

better suited for larger, public companies..<br />

The Philippines civil law system has long-standing common law aspects, found<br />

also in some contemporary European jurisdictions, in that its supreme court<br />

decisions are binding as precedents. The pre-1997 Philippines insolvency law dated<br />

from 1909 and included a rarely used liquidation procedure and a corporate rescue<br />

suspension of payments process taken from Spanish law that was available only to<br />

solvent companies experiencing temporary cash flow problems. Any proposal for<br />

debt rearrangement required the full payment of debts, and so was rarely used. A<br />

rehabilitation procedure was introduced as an alternative to the inflexible suspension<br />

of payment process under a 1976 presidential decree, later amended in 1981. Rather<br />

96. Lee Suet Lin Joyce, Is Singapore's Insolvency Regime Excessively Pro-Creditor?, 12 INT'L<br />

INSOLVENCY REV. 37 (2003) (discussing Singaporean corporate insolvency law).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 549 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

than giving jurisdiction for rehabilitation and suspension of payments to the<br />

judiciary, however, the amendment granted jurisdiction to the Securities and<br />

Exchange Commission (SEC). The rehabilitation procedure provided few rules and<br />

contained curiosities, such as providing that creditors were not obliged to approve a<br />

rehabilitation plan, and at times treating secured and unsecured creditors alike.<br />

Indonesian and Thai insolvency law also provided for liquidation and<br />

suspension of payments procedures, which were also rarely used. Indonesian<br />

debtors are able to present a plan of composition even within the liquidation process.<br />

The suspension of payments process provides the debtor with additional time to<br />

finalize a repayment plan. Under Thai bankruptcy law, composition is possible<br />

either pre-petition or post-petition. An unusual aspect of the Thai Bankruptcy Act<br />

1940 is that its presumption of insolvency appears to have been influenced by the<br />

acts of bankruptcy in 191h century English law.<br />

Taiwanese bankruptcy law dates from 1935 and provides for both liquidation<br />

and composition. The reorganization law under the Company <strong>Law</strong>, applicable to<br />

public companies, was similar to that in Korea. The reorganization law had not been<br />

amended in many years and was over-reliant on the court. The effectiveness of the<br />

old law has been criticized for its inconsistency "due in part to a lack of commercial<br />

viability on the part of the companies undergoing reorganization." 97 The lengthy<br />

reorganization process also enabled some companies to avoid bankruptcy by abusing<br />

the reorganization procedures. 8<br />

China was spared the most severe economic problems of the Asian financial<br />

crisis, and as of 1997 was the only jurisdiction in the study group whose bankruptcy<br />

laws had recently been promulgated. Nevertheless, at the time of the financial crisis,<br />

China was affected by domestic concerns resulting from the poor financial condition<br />

of its SOEs and state-owned banks. The insolvency framework in China at that<br />

time was an overlapping patchwork that included: a forty-three provision 1986<br />

Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong> for SOEs; eight provisions in Chapter XIX of the 1991 PRC Civil<br />

Procedure <strong>Law</strong> applicable to non-SOE enterprises with legal person status; judicial<br />

interpretations of these short laws, notably the 2002 interpretation by the Supreme<br />

People's Court; and most importantly, several policy decrees issued by the central<br />

government which are crucial in understanding the government's approach to<br />

insolvency issues. Although the number of insolvencies in China has been<br />

increasing, it is generally considered to be far lower than the number of insolvencies<br />

that would correspond to the true condition of most SOEs and banks, gauged by<br />

generally accepted accounting standards. A new bankruptcy law, under discussion<br />

for more than a decade, was finally enacted in August 2006 and is discussed below.<br />

Vietnam enacted a bankruptcy law in 1993 that came into operation in the<br />

following year. Unlike China's bifurcated approach-with separate laws for SOEs<br />

and non-SOE legal person enterprises,-Vietnam had a unified law. The<br />

Vietnamese law was also more expansive than the former Chinese act in that it also<br />

applied to enterprises lacking legal personality (e.g, partnerships and sole<br />

proprietorships).. In practice, however,, the law was cumbersome in application and<br />

rarely used. Its requirement that a debtor exhaust "all financial measures" before<br />

being eligible for bankruptcy effectively led to a two-year delay before a bankruptcy<br />

97. Eric Tsai & Hui-Erh Yuan, Taipei, China, in THE ASIA-PACIFIC RESTRUcTURING AND<br />

INSOLVENCY GUIDE 2006 154, 156 (2006).<br />

98. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 550 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 551<br />

could be commenced. A new Vietnamese bankruptcy law came into operation in<br />

2004." Cambodia is currently considering enactment of its first insolvency law.<br />

The profound impact of the 1997 crisis led to an immediate call to reform or<br />

replace archaic liquidation regimes and supplement them with modern corporate<br />

rescue procedures, including both formal court-based regimes and out-of-court and<br />

administrative procedures. Since the crisis, two waves of reform have crossed the<br />

region. The first included insolvency reforms in Indonesia, Malaysia, the<br />

Philippines, South Korea, Taiwan and Thailand. The second includes the new<br />

bankruptcy laws enacted in Vietnam in 2004 and China in 2006 and ongoing law<br />

reform efforts in Cambodia, Hong Kong, and Singapore, although the reform<br />

process in both China and Hong Kong began prior to mid-1997.<br />

2. Insolvency: Post-Financial Crisis Legal Reforms<br />

Thailand was among the states most severely affected by the 1997-98 financial<br />

crisis. A new chapter on business reorganization was added to the Bankruptcy Act in<br />

1998 to facilitate corporate rescues. One reform provided for the appointment of a<br />

bankruptcy planner to manage the affairs of the debtor company and prepare a plan<br />

of reorganization. The new procedure was intended for large corporate debtors<br />

owing at least BtlO million (US$273,000) to their creditors and further provisions<br />

would be appropriate to create an efficient procedure for smaller debtors. Further<br />

amendments were made to the bankruptcy law in 2000.<br />

An important part of the Thai reforms was the establishment of a bankruptcy<br />

court with exclusive jurisdiction for such cases pursuant to the 1999 Act for the<br />

Establishment of and Procedure for Bankruptcy Court. The act was amended in<br />

2004, while perceptions of the introduction of the bankruptcy courts have been<br />

varied. Initial views were positive, but concerns have increased as to the overall<br />

efficacy of these changes. There have been claims of inconsistency among individual<br />

courts; a fear that much of the expertise gained through the formation of the courts<br />

is lost when judges are rotated into other courts; an increasing backlog of cases; and<br />

there are concerns that corruption and fraud may be affecting the courts' work) 1 ° At<br />

present, these concerns appear to have eased somewhat and there is a re-emerging<br />

sense that the judicial reforms were for the best.<br />

Indonesia was more severely impacted by the 1997 crisis. In 1998, the<br />

Bankruptcy Ordinance was amended by a Government Regulation in Lieu of <strong>Law</strong>.<br />

Indonesia established a Commercial Court after the crisis to hear bankruptcy cases,<br />

but according to one commentator the court "has been beset by concerns of<br />

corruption and inconsistent application of the Bankruptcy Act"' 01 and "[t]he<br />

Indonesian Corruption Watch reports of corruption in the legal system is<br />

staggering."' ' 2 Many abuses have been publicized, with cases involving Canadian<br />

insurer Manulife and the Indonesian-controlled group APP (Asia Pulp & Paper) the<br />

99. See Charles Booth, Drafting Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>s in Socialist Market Economies: Recent<br />

Developments in China and Vietnam, 18 COLUM. J. ASIAN L. 93 (2004).<br />

100. Vassiliou, supra note 66, at 21.<br />

101. Lampros Vassiliou, The Asian Recovery: Progress and Pitfalls, Presented at the Global Forum on<br />

Insolvency Risk Management, Washington, DC (Jan. 28-29, 2003) at 6.<br />

102. Id. at 7.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 551 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

most well-known, having been the subject of much controversy and media coverage.<br />

However, the IMF and ADB funded a group of local lawyers and judges known as<br />

"Team 7" to address such problems and evaluate the Commercial Court's<br />

decisions." 3 Further amendments to Indonesian law were enacted in 2004.<br />

South Korea has made the most significant changes to the formal insolvency<br />

laws of all the jurisdictions in this study. Its corporate sector, especially the closelycontrolled<br />

chaebol conglomerates, was traditionally highly-leveraged, which proved<br />

an immediate burden in the light of a post-crisis withdrawal of available credit. South<br />

Korea agreed to enact substantial changes in law at the instigation of the IMF and<br />

World Bank in the form of amendments to its tripartite insolvency legislation<br />

covering liquidation, composition and reorganization. U.S. bankruptcy law<br />

influenced many of these changes. Among notable reforms was the inclusion of<br />

creditor committees in composition proceedings and management committees in<br />

reorganizations, while the time limit for reorganizations was halved from twenty to<br />

ten years. Many changes were intended to expedite reorganization procedures.<br />

Further amendments were made in 2000 and 2001, the latter including formalizing an<br />

out-of-court Workout Accord in the reorganization legislation to enable creditors to<br />

file proceedings to bind foreign creditors. A more recent major change to insolvency<br />

law was a Debtors' Rehabilitation and Bankruptcy Act (DRBA), which came into<br />

effect on April 1, 2006, and for the first time consolidated the three parallel<br />

insolvency acts. The new act further expedites corporate rescue processes, expands<br />

the reorganization system and abolishes the Composition Act. The task for South<br />

Korea may now be to ensure that its new legal framework is properly implemented,<br />

for which further practitioner training is likely to be necessary.<br />

Amendments to Philippines law were made in July 2000. Among the most<br />

significant changes was the transfer of jurisdiction for rehabilitation and suspension<br />

of payment cases from a state regulatory agency to the courts." Interim Rules of<br />

Procedure for Corporate Rehabilitation were promulgated in December 2000, in far<br />

more detailed form than the procedures under a prior Presidential Decree.<br />

Suspension of payment cases and corporate rehabilitation have become more<br />

common since the financial crisis, but delays remain a problem under the new regime<br />

obtaining post-petition financing has remained difficult. Other reforms are currently<br />

under discussion, notably a Corporate Recovery and Liquidation Act and a<br />

Corporate Recovery Act. It is hoped that the former includes a provision for fasttrack<br />

rehabilitation but congressional passage of these bills has been slow. The goal<br />

for the Philippines is also to increase the institutional capacity of the judiciary and of<br />

insolvency practitioners. Transferring jurisdiction for insolvency cases from the SEC<br />

to the courts is understandable, but it ensures that the Philippines is the sole<br />

jurisdiction in the study core where administrative and judicial enforcement capacity<br />

have decreased since the financial crisis. Another goal for the Philippines will be to<br />

better protect the rights of secured creditors.<br />

A reform of the Taiwanese Company <strong>Law</strong> in 2001 streamlined the<br />

reorganization procedures. These were the first major reforms to the procedures in<br />

roughly thirty years. Among the changes to the law were reducing the length of the<br />

reorganization process and requiring that companies using the procedures "be<br />

103. Id. at 35.<br />

104. See supra Part V(C)I.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 552 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 553<br />

capable of being revived through reorganisation.' ' 5 It has been noted that several<br />

successful reorganizations have recently been carried out and that the changes have<br />

enhanced the viability of the new law as a restructuring tool and reduced the<br />

incentives for debtors to abuse the reorganization process.' Further changes to the<br />

insolvency laws are also being considered, including a proposal to unify the<br />

bankruptcy and reorganization laws into a single code.<br />

In August 2006, China enacted a new insolvency law that came into operation<br />

in June 2007. This new law is the result of an insolvency law reform process that<br />

dates back to 1994. This law applies to all legal person enterprises and unifies the<br />

existing patchwork of bankruptcy laws, decrees, and judicial interpretations. This<br />

new law radically improves both the liquidation and corporate rescue processes. At<br />

the heart of these reforms is the introduction of an office of the professional<br />

administrator to replace the current inefficient liquidation team model. The new law<br />

includes a detailed corporate rescue process that draws heavily on Chapter 11 of the<br />

U.S. Bankruptcy Act (for example, providing for post-petition financing and a<br />

limited cramdown). These procedures will allow for reorganizations led either by<br />

the administrator or a debtor-in-possession (under the supervision of the<br />

administrator).<br />

The main substantive issue delaying the enactment of the new law was a<br />

conflict as to how to resolve the interests of secured creditors and employees in cases<br />

where company funds prove insufficient to meet wages in full. A compromise was<br />

reached providing that secured creditors will have priority over all workers' claims<br />

arising after August 27, 2006, but that certain wage, medical, and insurance claims of<br />

workers arising before that date will have priority over the claims of secured<br />

creditors. Another controversial issue during the drafting process was whether<br />

SOEs should be made subject to the new law. The new law provides that special<br />

matters regarding the bankruptcy of SOEs shall no longer continue to be handled<br />

under <strong>State</strong> Council regulations. Time will tell whether that will be the case.<br />

In reforming its insolvency law, Vietnam was interested in China's approach to<br />

similar issues. When both Vietnam and China issued new draftlaws in 2002, the<br />

former was at an earlier stage of development. However, Vietnam avoided the<br />

contentious delays that occurred in China and enacted its law in 2004. This<br />

abolished the former requirements that a debtor must first exhaust "all financial<br />

measures" to become eligible for bankruptcy relief, and represents a significant<br />

reform. However, in comparison to China, Vietnam's reform approach was<br />

gradualist, lacks a "driver" of the new legal process (i.e., does not have an official<br />

equivalent to the Chinese administrator), and has fewer checks and balances.<br />

Attempts at Hong Kong insolvency law reform pre-date the 1997 financial<br />

crisis. In 1996 the Hong Kong <strong>Law</strong> Reform Commission set out the framework for a<br />

new regime, by which a qualified specialist called a "provisional supervisor" would<br />

after commencement of the process take control of the company and be responsible<br />

for drafting a proposal for creditor agreement. The first draft bill was gazetted in<br />

2000, and offered many advantages over current law, but a primary flaw has been a<br />

proposal that employees' salaries be paid in full or sufficient funds placed in trust for<br />

105. Tsai & Yuan, supra note 97, at 156.<br />

106. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 553 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

the purpose. °7 Fortunately, in a line of cases beginning in 2002, the judiciary was<br />

receptive to the use of provisional liquidation as a mechanism to facilitate corporate<br />

rescue. However, the use of provisional liquidation to assist with corporate rescue<br />

was narrowly re-interpreted in the recent case of Re Legend International Resorts<br />

Ltd., which required that a company's assets first be in jeopardy for a provisional<br />

liquidator to be appointed." 8 The enactment of a provisional supervision regime in<br />

the foreseeable future is quite unlikely."<br />

Singapore's insolvency regime is currently the most comprehensive of the study<br />

group. For more than five years, schemes of arrangements have proven more<br />

popular than judicial management cases. Among the reasons are that a stay on<br />

unsecured creditor action in the scheme of arrangement procedure gives the debtor<br />

company sufficient time to proceed to propose such a scheme; it can remain in<br />

possession of assets and equipment; and less adverse publicity and commercial<br />

stigma appears to arise in relation to a scheme of arrangement than from many<br />

judicial management cases. As with Hong Kong and Malaysian law, a weakness of<br />

Singapore's model is the bifurcation of corporate insolvency procedures in company<br />

law, and the personal insolvency procedures in bankruptcy law. Singapore is<br />

considering the enactment of unified legislation to address this problem, but this will<br />

not take place in the short term.<br />

3. Insolvency: Post-Financial Crisis Out-of-Court Reforms<br />

Although legal insolvency reforms received much attention due to the needs<br />

created by the Asian financial crisis, the time taken to enact and implement any such<br />

legislation is inevitably protracted. While legislative reforms were first considered,<br />

other efforts began to save companies whose businesses could create value for<br />

creditors and other stakeholders. These efforts led to two types of reforms, the first<br />

being the promulgation of out-of-court workout procedures based on the London<br />

°<br />

Approach.' These included the Bangkok Approach, Malaysia's Corporate Debt<br />

Restructuring Committee (CDRC), the Hong Kong Approach, the Jakarta<br />

Initiative, and the Workout Accord in South Korea. In contrast to the general<br />

experience in Europe, this semi-formal approach has been successful in cases where<br />

the parties involved are overwhelmingly of a single domicile. Still, they have been<br />

only modestly helpful in Asia's many post-1998 cross-border multi-creditor<br />

restructurings, despite a large number of such cases being managed by banks<br />

operating in Hong Kong." 1<br />

More radically, where national banking sectors were severely affected by<br />

delinquent loans, the second alternative provided for establishment of administrative<br />

107. See Philip Smart & Charles Booth, Reforming Corporate Rescue Procedures in Hong Kong, 1 J.<br />

OF CORP. L. STUD. 485 (2001); Booth, supra note 99.<br />

108. [2006] HKCA 67; CACV000207/2005, Mar. 1, 2006.<br />

109. See Charles Booth, The Race of Two Tortoises: Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> Reform in Hong Kong and<br />

China, CHINA L. REP., Nov. 2006, at 3.<br />

110. See supra note 93 and accompanying text, but note that the "the effectiveness of such semivoluntary<br />

arrangements has been eroded by the growing use of loan sales and other forms of credit risk<br />

transfer"; see BERRY HSU ET AL., FINANCIAL MARKETS IN HONG KONG: LAW & PRACTICE 154 (2006).<br />

Outside Asia, the practice has influenced the recent development of protocols for the settlement of credit<br />

default swaps.<br />

111. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 554 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 555<br />

asset management agencies to assist with the restructuring and disposal of NPLs,<br />

including the Indonesian Bank Restructuring Agency (IBRA), Malaysia's<br />

Pengurusan Danaharta Nasional Bhd (Danaharta), and the Thai Asset Management<br />

Company (TAMC). For the most part, these entities were created as part of<br />

emergency measures and several are in the process of being shut down." 2<br />

Hong Kong established its Hong Kong Approach to Corporate Difficulties in<br />

1999, modeled on the London Approach, with the backing of the self-regulated<br />

Hong Kong Association of Banks and the government's Hong Kong Monetary<br />

Authority.<br />

South Korea established an out-of-court workout process in June 1998, in the<br />

form of a Workout Accord among financial intermediaries. The process was<br />

imperfect, though, as it excluded foreign creditors and provided no priority for postcommencement<br />

financing. In 2001 the Workout Accord procedure was promulgated<br />

as part of the reorganization law to address these two problems and formally expired<br />

on December 31, 2005. The Korean Asset Management Company (KAMCO)<br />

assisted in resolving the commercial banking sector's sizeable accumulation of NPLs.<br />

Unlike similar Asian asset management companies (AMCs), KAMCO was not a<br />

temporary entity established to deal with the 1997 crisis, and had been formed in<br />

1962. Indonesia established the Jakarta Initiative to assist with out-of-court<br />

restructuring and set up IBRA to deal with the impaired assets of Indonesian<br />

financial intermediaries. IBRA became very substantial, and was the largest<br />

national landowner before its dissolution in 2004."' Its results were less effective<br />

than those of state-sponsored AMCs elsewhere, notably KAMCO or Danaharta, in<br />

particular due to a policy of acquiring distressed assets at inflated balance sheet<br />

prices rather than establish a realistic market value-even though the payments<br />

made to the transferor banks were not necessarily of the same order.<br />

Malaysia established CDRC to assist with informal out-of-court rescues and an<br />

asset management entity (Danaharta) to assist with problems encountered by the<br />

financial sector. Danaharta had strong powers of enforcement and its results are still<br />

viewed as important in addressing post-crisis problems in Malaysia.<br />

In 1998, the Bank of Thailand established an informal out-of-court<br />

restructuring procedure for financial creditors known as the Bangkok Approach,<br />

headed by the Corporate Debt Restructuring Advisory Committee. TAMC was<br />

created pursuant to emergency legislation in June 2001 to assist in the disposal of<br />

financial sector NPLs.<br />

China established four AMCs to address accumulated NPLs at each of the<br />

largest state-owned commercial banks. The first, China Xinda Asset Management<br />

Company (Cinda) for Construction Bank of China and China Development Bank,<br />

was formed in April 1999. It was followed by China Huarong Asset Management<br />

Corporation for Industrial and Commercial Bank of China, Dongfang Asset<br />

Management Company (Oriental) for Bank of China, and China Great Wall Asset<br />

Management Company for Agricultural Bank of China. Regional AMCs were also<br />

112. The forerunner model of these entities was the U.S. Resolution Trust Corporation, which from<br />

1989-95 acted as a federal asset disposal conduit for failed savings and loan and other housing finance<br />

organizations.<br />

113. Vassiliou, supra note 101, at 35.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 555 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

established, including the important Guangdong Guangye Asset Management<br />

Company.<br />

Like China, Vietnam established AMCs connected to the commercial banks to<br />

dispose of NPLs. In addition, Vietnam established a national Debts and Assets<br />

Trading Company managed by the Ministry of Finance.<br />

Taiwan also has established AMCs to assist with the disposal of NPLs through<br />

the promulgation of the Financial Institutions Merger Act of 2000.<br />

4. Interaction between Creditor Rights and Insolvency<br />

A theme of this study is that effective insolvency regimes go hand-in-hand with<br />

effective secured transaction regimes. This parallel development of secured<br />

transaction laws is absent from most of the jurisdictions considered. The overall<br />

implementation of insolvency regimes throughout the region would benefit from the<br />

improvement or introduction of effective secured transactions systems, for it is<br />

within insolvency cases that the integrity of secured transactions and the rights of<br />

secured creditors are fully tested.<br />

The English system of company law adapted in Hong Kong, Malaysia, and<br />

Singapore puts secured creditors in a relatively strong position in insolvency matters,<br />

and there is thus a high level of predictability as to the rights of secured creditors in<br />

these three jurisdictions. Secured creditors act outside a liquidation and are not<br />

subject to a general stay against creditors. Unless agreed otherwise, they also act<br />

outside any scheme-of-arrangement process. It is only in judicial management cases<br />

in Singapore that secured creditors are made subject to the general stay.<br />

TABLE 8: COMPATIBILITY OF CREDITOR RIGHTS AND INSOLVENCY<br />

SYSTEMS<br />

Compatibility<br />

of systems<br />

relating to<br />

Principal source and Form of legal creditor rights<br />

system of current law' transplant and those<br />

permitting<br />

secured<br />

transactions<br />

Cambodia French civil Imposition NA<br />

China... Mixed (German civil; Adoption 1/2<br />

Socialist)<br />

Indonesia Dutch civil Imposition 1/2<br />

Malaysia English common Imposition 3/4<br />

114. For guidance only: questions of legal inheritance or transplant are beyond the direct scope of this<br />

article. The indications given in Table 8 take no real account of mixed jurisdictions, or of what has been<br />

termed "chthonic law," whether ancient or contemporary. See H. PATRICK GLENN, LEGAL TRADITIONS<br />

OF THE WORLD: SUSTAINABLE DIVERSITY IN LAW 58-114 (2004).<br />

115. In regard to the recently enacted bankruptcy law that came into operation in June 2007.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 556 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 557<br />

Philippines Mixed (Spanish civil; U.S.) Imposition 1/2<br />

South Korea German civil Mixed 3/4<br />

Taiwan German, Japanese civil Imposition / 3/4<br />

adoption<br />

Thailand French civil Adoption 1/2<br />

Vietnam Mixed (French civil; Imposition / 1<br />

Socialist)<br />

adoption<br />

Hong Kong English common Imposition 4/5<br />

Singapore English common Imposition 4/5<br />

In China, the rights of a secured creditor historically have depended upon<br />

whether a bankruptcy case is entered pursuant to government policy decrees or<br />

bankruptcy laws, though the new bankruptcy law claims to bring this distinction to<br />

an end. Under the old regime, there was a traditional priority scheme in the<br />

bankruptcy laws whereby employee claims ranked after those of secured creditors.<br />

In contrast, in policy bankruptcies, secured creditors could lose priority in land-use<br />

rights and other secured assets to employees, so as to assist the latter with<br />

resettlement and other entitlements. However, as noted above, under the recently<br />

agreed compromise, the new Chinese bankruptcy law provides that secured<br />

creditors will have priority over all workers' claims arising after August 27, 2006, but<br />

that certain wage, medical, and insurance claims of workers arising before that date<br />

will have priority over the claims of secured creditors. Although secured creditors<br />

are subject to a stay in liquidations and reorganizations, they retain priority in<br />

payment to the extent of their collateral.<br />

In summary, China, Indonesia, the Philippines, and Vietnam adopt the U.S.<br />

approach by which secured creditors are subject to an automatic stay in both<br />

liquidations and reorganizations. In contrast, in South Korea, Singapore, and<br />

Thailand, secured creditors are subject to a moratorium in reorganizations, but not<br />

in liquidations or compositions. Last, secured creditors of companies in Hong Kong,<br />

Malaysia, and Taiwan may act unilaterally outside both bankruptcy and<br />

reorganization. In jurisdictions where secured creditors are subject to an automatic<br />

stay, the courts have rarely applied principles of adequate protection when those<br />

6<br />

creditors seek to be exempt. In the Philippines, less account is taken than<br />

elsewhere of the views of secured creditors in the preparation and sanction of<br />

reorganization plans. In some instances, secured creditors have been required to<br />

share pari passu with unsecured creditors.<br />

Two main areas of law in the interaction of secured creditors and insolvency<br />

needing improvement in most jurisdictions are first, protection for secured creditors<br />

seeking exemption from the automatic stay; and second, limiting employee priority<br />

in claims over properly established secured interests.<br />

116. Vasiliou, supra note 101, at 8.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 557 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

5. Summary<br />

In an immediate post-crisis review of regional insolvency law reforms, the ADB<br />

found that the number of insolvency cases remained low in Indonesia, Malaysia, the<br />

Philippines, South Korea, and Thailand, despite rising from pre-crisis levels.<br />

Indonesia, the Philippines, and Thailand were identified as having "extraordinarily<br />

low" liquidations, and Indonesia and Thailand were identified as jurisdictions in<br />

which the use of new formal reorganization laws was surprisingly low. Liquidations<br />

were most numerous in South Korea and Malaysia, with Malaysia having more.<br />

South Korea had by far the greatest number of reorganizations, but lower than<br />

might have been predicted based on national output losses in 1997-98.<br />

The review also found that out-of-court processes were used far more often<br />

than formal insolvency laws except in South Korea, where their overall use was also<br />

7<br />

"surprisingly low... Data for the study were obtained from observations up to mid-<br />

1999, but subsequent anecdotal observations support these findings. It remains<br />

difficult to obtain accurate insolvency case data from most jurisdictions in Asia, and<br />

harder still to locate accurate assessments of out-of-court workouts. However, case<br />

data may not be the sole benchmark of success. One benefit of enacting formal<br />

corporate rescue laws is that by setting outvoting minimums and implementation<br />

requirements for reorganization plans, a framework for extra-judicial negotiations<br />

is created that addresses problems of the type caused by intransigent holdout<br />

creditors, both before and since the region's financial crisis. If recalcitrant creditors<br />

currently use such tactics, a debtor or creditor may threaten formal insolvency<br />

proceedings so as to cause the holdout creditor to be outvoted.<br />

The ADB study demonstrates that the promulgation of new insolvency laws is<br />

only part of achieving an effective insolvency system. Although a new law may be<br />

modern in design and enacted to facilitate corporate rescue, its impact will take time<br />

to discern. In contrast, the benefits from enabling out-of-court rescue processes<br />

have typically been more immediate.<br />

Of the core jurisdictions discussed in this article, implementation of an effective<br />

corporate insolvency regime is best achieved in Singapore and Hong Kong, which<br />

are also the jurisdictions that have made the least changes to their laws since the<br />

1997-98 crisis. Hong Kong is unusual in that while it lacks an effective formal<br />

corporate rescue law, it scores highly, largely due to the adaptation of the provisional<br />

liquidation procedure and the creativity of judiciary and insolvency practitioners in<br />

crafting out-of-court corporate rescues. The main goals for both Hong Kong and<br />

Malaysia remain the need to enact modern corporate rescue systems and to update<br />

aspects of liquidation procedures. The latter is also relevant for Singapore and most<br />

other countries examined here. It is expected that Cambodia will soon enact a<br />

modern insolvency law.<br />

The demand following the enactment of formal insolvency laws is to stimulate<br />

human resources through greater judicial competence as well as training effective<br />

insolvency practitioners. Specialized courts or benches are valuable but experiences<br />

in Indonesia and Thailand demonstrate that the creation of such courts is not a<br />

panacea. It is important for the judiciary to strive for consistency, and to eliminate<br />

corruption and the trading of influence. Professional and judicial training are crucial<br />

in this process. Another important feature of strengthening the implementation of<br />

117. See Report on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> Reforms, supra note 65, at 10-11, 70-75.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 558 2006-2007


2007 PROPERTY RIGHTS, COLLATERAL, CREDITOR RIGHTS, AND INSOLVENCY 559<br />

the law is the development of a government agency to regulate insolvency processes.<br />

The Official Receiver's Office in Hong Kong and the Official Assignee's offices in<br />

Malaysia and Singapore each perform this function effectively. It is also crucial for<br />

practitioners to discuss regularly contemporary insolvency developments among<br />

themselves and with national regulators. Hong Kong currently offers a good<br />

example of such interaction, which contributes to the overall effectiveness of the<br />

sector. <strong>Law</strong>yers and accountants meet regularly for training sessions run by the<br />

Insolvency Interest Group, housed in the Hong Kong Institute of Certified<br />

Professional Accountants. The latter runs insolvency training courses including an<br />

advanced diploma course that is recognized by the Official Receiver's Office. Such<br />

arrangements could serve as a model for the region.<br />

The activities of the World Bank and UNCITRAL show that there is no single<br />

set of provisions for an effective insolvency regime. Nonetheless, three issues have<br />

commonly caused difficulties in the implementation of new insolvency laws in the<br />

region. First, the granting of over-generous priority or preference to employees can<br />

lead to an unconstructive response by secured creditors and ultimately adversely<br />

affect bank lending and secured transactions. Second, it may be a serious<br />

disincentive for many officers and directors of distressed companies to be replaced<br />

immediately by an outside administrator, especially among smaller family-controlled<br />

companies that are seeking relief from creditors. Last, the commencement criteria<br />

should be as clear as possible, for example, avoiding balance sheet insolvency tests<br />

that may rely on imperfect accounting standards.<br />

VI. CONTRACT ENFORCEMENT AND DISPUTE RESOLUTION<br />

The most critical neglect throughout the region is in enforcement and<br />

implementation, with the partial exceptions of Hong Kong and Singapore.<br />

According to Haselman, Pistor, and Vig:<br />

The major function attributed to law is that it empowers creditors to<br />

enforce their contracts. Effective legal institutions reduce the risk of<br />

lending and therefore result in greater lending volume in an economy as a<br />

share of GDP. Implicit in this view of how law affects economic outcome<br />

is that all actors in the economy benefit from better law."'<br />

This may suggest that the law matters less than its enforcement. Both theory<br />

and experience support this position. Coase was first to describe the importance of<br />

delineation and enforcement of commercial contracts, in analyses based upon<br />

observations of industrial practice." 9 In an environment of imperfect markets with<br />

real transaction costs, parties will seek efficient results through contracting.<br />

Unfortunately, transaction costs extend to the expense of enforcement, without<br />

which contracting cannot produce solutions to market imperfections nor lead to<br />

stable long-term outcomes. Rather, contracting will tend towards sub-optimal<br />

instantaneous transactions such as barter, which is in part a state from which the<br />

least developed members of the study core have recently emerged.<br />

118. Haselmann, Pistor & Vig, supra note 38.<br />

119. See Coase, supra note 43; R. H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3J. L. & ECON. 1 (1960).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 559 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:515<br />

The enforcement of contracts requires a system of governance capable of<br />

producing, applying, and policing effective solutions. Part II of this article showed<br />

that a range of such systems may be theoretically capable of producing this result,<br />

and history has provided many disparate examples. Enforcement of contracts is not<br />

synonymous with the existence of the rule of law, but just one component of a<br />

system that can be so described. The rule of law is not a precondition for a market<br />

economy, despite generally being considered an important factor in economic<br />

development and highly conducive to financial market development. Yet a<br />

governance system that enforces contracts and resolves commercial disputes in a<br />

credible and predictable manner is essential to a basic market economy, as well as<br />

allowing financial markets to develop beyond the simplest single instantaneous<br />

transactions. This is important for institutional concerns such as the enforcement of<br />

financial contracts, efficient insolvency, and collateral systems, and dispute<br />

resolution procedures. In this context, mechanisms for contract enforcement and<br />

resolving commercial disputes may also be more important than specific laws.<br />

There are four further concerns. First, broadening the availability of real<br />

property ownership and mechanisms to support its use, especially relating to<br />

enforcement and commercial dispute resolution mechanisms. Second, the need<br />

more simply to delineate the provisions for secured transactions, in particular to<br />

provide for security interests in intangible property. Third, the development of<br />

effective registration systems to cover a range of assets, including real property,<br />

security, and intangibles, and to simplify the use and availability of collateral and its<br />

enforcement, leading to reductions in transactions costs. Last, where judicial systems<br />

for enforcement and dispute resolution are ineffective, the support of appropriate<br />

mechanisms for creditor and debtor self-assistance deserve, provided that they are<br />

transparently fair and just. This includes encouraging greater use of commercial<br />

arbitration.<br />

The foregoing Tables 2, 5, 7, and 8 show that most jurisdictions addressed in<br />

this Article have developed generally acceptable laws relating to creditor rights and<br />

insolvency but have failed fully to reform their collateral and secured transaction<br />

regimes. At the same time, where such insolvency or collateral laws have been<br />

enacted, few jurisdictions have been effective in their implementation and<br />

enforcement. This is the concern to which legislative and administrative attention<br />

needs to be devoted and which clearly demonstrates the linkage between effective<br />

governance, economic, and legal systems and property, collateral, and creditor rights<br />

in East Asia.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 560 2006-2007


Negotiation in Letter of Credit Practice and<br />

<strong>Law</strong>: The Evolution of the Doctrine<br />

PROFESSOR JAMES E. BYRNE*<br />

ABSTRACT<br />

The concept of negotiation in letter of credit practice and law has evolved from being<br />

an appendage of the law of negotiable instruments to an independent discipline that<br />

often alters basic assumptions of negotiable instruments law. From playing a central<br />

role in the letter of credit process, the draft or bill of exchange has become incidental<br />

and atrophied. Indeed, with respect to banks nominated in the letter of credit to<br />

"negotiate," negotiation can occur without there being a draft or bill of exchange.<br />

Nonetheless, negotiation, as used in letters of credit, is an important aspect of letter of<br />

credit practice, enabling it to serve as a means of trade facilitation and finance. The<br />

latest revision of the Uniform Customs and Practice for Documentary Credits,<br />

UCP600, reflects the currency of this concept in its attempts to define "negotiation"<br />

and to clarify its role in letter of credit practice.<br />

This paper surveys and compares the concept of negotiation in both fields. It<br />

summarizes the law of negotiable instruments (Part I), studying, analyzing, and<br />

comparing negotiation in letter of credit practice (Part II), It then considers important<br />

issues that arise in the negotiation of LCs, such as the requirement of a draft,<br />

formalities, recourse, and letter of credit fraud (Part III), and ends by suggesting an<br />

approach to the definition of "negotiation" in letter of credit practice and law (Part<br />

IV).<br />

* Professor Byrne teaches law at George Mason University School of <strong>Law</strong> and directs the Institute of<br />

International Banking <strong>Law</strong> & Practice, Inc. He has played important roles in connection with the reform<br />

of letter of credit law and practice on the national and international levels, including the revision of U.C.C.<br />

Article 5, the International Standby Practices, and the United Nations Convention on Independent<br />

Guarantees and Stand-by Letters of Credit. The support of George Mason University School of <strong>Law</strong> and<br />

its <strong>Law</strong> & Economics Center in the research necessary to prepare this Article and the active collaboration<br />

of attorney Lee H. Davis, Senior Attorney for the Institute of International Banking <strong>Law</strong> & Practice, is<br />

gratefully acknowledged. While I have not consulted with colleagues regarding the text of this paper, their<br />

ideas and insights form a part of my thought process and, in this sense, they will recognize these things,<br />

hopefully well digested. In particular, Mr. James G. Barnes, Professor Boris Kozolchyk, Professor E. Peter<br />

Ellinger, and Mr. Vincent Maulella have over recent years discussed issues with me that are addressed in<br />

this paper and, while not seeking to taint them with the outcome, I thank them for their friendship,<br />

patience, and willingness to seek a conceptual consensus. Hopefully, this work will contribute to it.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 561 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

It suggests that negotiation - whether by a bank that undertakes to do so in its letter of<br />

credit undertaking or by a bank nominated to do so without having made such an<br />

undertaking-gives rise to a basis of liability that is separate and preemptive from, if<br />

sometimes parallel to, that which arises on negotiable instrument that may be involved.<br />

Although the letter of credit concept of negotiation readily borrows from the law of<br />

negotiable instruments with respect to protection of the right to a protected status,<br />

important differences arise based on the nature of the letter of credit undertaking.<br />

Where there is a letter of credit undertaking to negotiate, negotiation is the means by<br />

which the bank honors its letter of credit obligation to the beneficiary, taking up the<br />

documents presented and any draft, and discounting the amount due to present value<br />

in the event of a time obligation without any right to seek recourse against the<br />

beneficiary. Where there is no undertaking, a bank that negotiates pursuant to a<br />

nomination is the transferee of the right to the proceeds of the letter of credit.<br />

SUMMARY<br />

1. SURVEY OF NEGOTIATION OF DRAFTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE<br />

IN STR U M EN TS ...................................................................................................... 563<br />

II. NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE ............................................ 565<br />

A . Pre-U CP400 Term inology .......................................................................... 565<br />

B. Post-UCP400 Term inology ................. ...................................................... 567<br />

III. ISSUES REGARDING NEGOTIATION OF LCs ..................................................... 570<br />

A . The Requirem ent of a D raft ....................................................................... 570<br />

B . Form ality R equirem ents ............................................................................. 572<br />

C . W ho N egotiates? .......................................................................................... 575<br />

D . H ow D oes Negotiation Occur? .................................................................. 575<br />

E . R eco u rse ....................................................................................................... 577<br />

F. Protection of Banks That Negotiate in the Event of LC Fraud .............. 579<br />

1. The Presumption of Entitlement ........................................................ 580<br />

2. What Defense is Good Against a Beneficiary? The LC Fraud<br />

Exception to the Independence Principle ......................................... 581<br />

3. The LC Exception to the Fraud Defense: Protected Persons ......... 584<br />

4. N om in ation ............................................................................................ 585<br />

a. Protected Status Where There Is Negotiation by the Issuing<br />

or C onfirm ing B ank ...................................................................... 586<br />

b. Protected Status Where There Is Negotiation by a<br />

N egotiating B ank .......................................................................... 588<br />

5 . V alu e ...................................................................................................... 588<br />

6 . N o tice ..................................................................................................... 593<br />

IV. TOWARDS A DEFINITION OF LC NEGOTIATION .............................................. 593<br />

V . C O N CLU SIO N ....................................................................................................... 594<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 562 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

I. SURVEY OF NEGOTIATION OF DRAFTS IN THE LAW OF<br />

NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS'<br />

Negotiation in the law of negotiable instruments is a special transfer of<br />

intangible rights in a negotiable instrument, which entitles the transferee to claim<br />

under the instrument as if it were payable directly to it, transfer it in a similar<br />

manner to others, and claim under appropriate circumstances that it takes free of<br />

certain defenses that could have been raised against the drawer or prior transferees. 2<br />

1. While both bills of exchange and promises can be negotiable instruments, this paper deals<br />

exclusively with the former since letters of credit (hereinafter LCs) do not use promissory notes in<br />

connection with their negotiability. For convenience, the term "draft" is used in this article rather than<br />

"bill of exchange," since it is the term that has been chiefly used in the Uniform Customs and Practice for<br />

Documentary Credits (hereinafter UCP). "Draft" is not used in the U.K. Bills of Exchange Act, 1882, 45<br />

& 46 Vict. c. 61, § 2, but is used in U.S. statutory law. See, e.g., U.C.C. § 3-104(e) (2006). A draft or bill of<br />

exchange is a formal order to pay money. Id. §3-104(a)-(b), (e). Although the first two versions of the<br />

UCP used the term "draft" without mention of the term "bill of exchange," see UCP82 (1933), UCP151<br />

(1951), the 1962 Revision used the term "bill of exchange," signifying that it meant "draft" by the use of a<br />

parenthetical and thereafter used the word "draft." UCP222 (1962). UCP222 General Provisions and<br />

Definitions (b) provides that "a bank ... is to pay, accept, or negotiate bills of exchange (drafts) drawn by<br />

the beneficiary .... " The 2007 Revision continues this tradition by inserting the parenthetical in Article 2<br />

(Definitions), paragraph 9, "Honour," providing that the meaning of "honour" includes "to accept a bill of<br />

exchange ('draft') drawn by .... " UCP600 (2007). Which term is used in practice depends on the<br />

discipline involved, tradition, and the names used in local law. The term "bill of exchange" is older, but<br />

"draft" has a long tradition of use. The word "bill" is derived from the Latin "bulla," which was used to<br />

describe an ornament or a bubble. A bulla was worn by aristocratic Roman youths until they assumed<br />

manhood. THE OXFORD ENGLISH DICTIONARY, (J.A. Simpson & E.S.C. Weiner eds., 2d ed. 1989) links<br />

its use in English to the seal with which documents were authenticated and reports the first use of it in the<br />

sense of an order to pay in 1579. The word "draft" is a derivative of the word "draught" (sometime<br />

rendered in later Medieval English as "drawt," which makes the linkage clearer). Its first reported use in<br />

the sense of an order to pay money was in 1633. Blackstone states that "[in common speech, such a bill is<br />

frequently called a draught, but a bill of exchange is the more legal as well as mercantile expression."<br />

WILLIAM BLACKSTONE, 2 COMMENTARIES *467. Although there are some technical differences, the<br />

terms are effectively interchangeable. The principal difference between a classical bill of exchange and a<br />

draft is that the bill of exchange is a four-party instrument stating the name of the remitter, whereas a draft<br />

is typically a three-party instrument stating only the name of the drawer, drawee, and payee. Except for<br />

emphasis where both terms are used, the term "draft" will be used in this paper to signify either a draft or<br />

bill of exchange. The terms "draft" and "bill of exchange" are used commonly (but not necessarily) to<br />

signify an undertaking that meets the formal requirements of negotiable instruments law to qualify as a<br />

negotiable instrument.<br />

2. See U.C.C. § 3-201 (2006) (stating that "'[n]egotiation' means a transfer of possession, whether<br />

voluntary or involuntary, of an instrument by a person other than the issuer to a person who thereby<br />

becomes its holder .... Except for negotiation by a remitter, if an instrument is payable to an identified<br />

person, negotiation requires transfer of possession of the instrument and its indorsement by the holder. If<br />

an instrument is payable to bearer, it may be negotiated by transfer of possession alone"); United Nations<br />

Convention on International Bills of Exchange and International Promissory Notes, G.A. Res. 43/165, art.<br />

13, U.N. Doc. A/RES/43/165 (Dec. 9, 1988) [hereinafter U.N. Bills of Exchange Convention] (stating that<br />

"[a]n instrument is transferred: (a) By endorsement and delivery of the instrument by the endorser to the<br />

endorsee; or (b) By mere delivery of the instrument if the last endorsement is in blank"); Bills of Exchange<br />

Act art. 31 (stating that "[a] bill is negotiated when it is transferred from one person to another in such a<br />

manner as to constitute the transferee the holder of the bill"); The Convention Providing a Uniform <strong>Law</strong><br />

for Bills of Exchange and Promissory Notes, League of Nations, art. 11, June 7, 1930, reg. no. 3313<br />

[hereinafter Geneva Convention on Bills of Exchange] (stating that "[e]very bill of exchange, even if not<br />

expressly drawn to order, may be transferred by means of endorsement"); art. 14 (stating that "[a]n<br />

endorsement transfers all the rights arising out of a bill of exchange"). Negotiable instruments law marks a<br />

unique intersection of the law of property and commerce in which the rights of ownership are embodied or<br />

merged in the special piece of paper. See PETER ELLINGER, Negotiable Instruments, in 9 INTERNATIONAL<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 563 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

While there are differences as to how one becomes entitled to exercise these<br />

rights, these differences have little practical significance in discussing negotiability in<br />

connection with letters of credit, and the common law and civil law identify this<br />

person as a "holder." 3<br />

Negotiation in the law of negotiable instruments has certain formal<br />

prerequisites. Not just any promise or order to pay can be negotiated. To be<br />

negotiated, it must be in the form of a negotiable instrument-it must meet certain<br />

formal requirements, which include being unconditional. 4<br />

Because the concept of negotiation necessarily involves the use of abstract<br />

terminology drawn from the major legal regimes, it is easier to explain how<br />

negotiation occurs than what it is. Negotiation of a negotiable instrument always<br />

entails the delivery of the instrument to an entity who becomes a holder. Where the<br />

instrument is issued in bearer form or indorsed in blank or to bearer, only delivery is<br />

required to effect a negotiation. Where the instrument is issued to the order of a<br />

named entity or entities or issued in bearer form and indorsed to a named entity or<br />

its order, the delivery must be accompanied by the indorsement of that entity<br />

By issuing a negotiable instrument as a drawer or by indorsing it, an entity<br />

makes certain promises to subsequent holders to whom the instrument is negotiated<br />

or who can claim as a transferee of such a person, namely that it will honor the<br />

instrument if it is dishonored on maturity by the drawee or a subsequent indorser<br />

provided that any necessary notice is given. 6 To disclaim this obligation on the<br />

instrument, it is necessary to indicate that the indorsement (or issuance) is "without<br />

recourse." An indorsement or issuance without recourse signifies that in the event<br />

of its dishonor by the drawee, there is no recourse available on the instrument<br />

against the indorser or issuer. Absent such a disclaimer, it is assumed that any<br />

person signing an instrument as drawer or indorser makes such an undertaking.<br />

In the case of a negotiable instrument, negotiation is undertaken by the entity<br />

that is in possession of the instrument to whom it runs (holder) and is transferring<br />

(negotiating) it. One would typically speak of negotiation by the transferor and not<br />

by the transferee. It is the transferee to whom the negotiable instrument is<br />

negotiated.<br />

ENCYCLOPEDIA OF COMPARATIVE LAW, (Jacob S. Ziegel ed., 2000). While some of the property law<br />

features of negotiable instruments are retained in letters of credit, they are less fixed, and the undertaking<br />

is closer to its commercial law antecedents. Id.<br />

3. See ELLINGER, supra note 2, §§ 404-27.<br />

4. U.C.C. § 3-104(a) (2006) (stating that "'negotiable instrument' means an unconditional promise or<br />

order to pay a fixed amount of money"); U.N. Bills of Exchange Convention, supra note 2, art. 3 (stating<br />

that "a bill of exchange is a written instrument which: (a) Contains an unconditional order whereby the<br />

drawer directs the drawee to pay a definite sum of money to the payee or to his order"); Geneva<br />

Convention on Bills of Exchange, supra note 2, art. 1 (stating that "[a] bill of exchange contains: ... 2. An<br />

unconditional order to pay a determinate sum of money"); Bills of Exchange Act art. 3 (stating that "[a]<br />

bill of exchange is an unconditional order in writing, addressed by one person to another, signed by the<br />

person giving it, requiring the person to whom it is addressed to pay on demand or at a fixed or<br />

determinable future time a sum certain in money to the order of a specified person, or to bearer").<br />

5. The civil law, unlike the common law, would require only regularity of appearance in the<br />

indorsements regardless of whether they are genuine. ELLINGER, supra note 2, § 416.<br />

6. This obligation operates when a negotiable instrument is issued or negotiated by indorsement.<br />

Under some systems of law, it is impacted or even discharged by a subsequent acceptance of the<br />

instrument. See U.C.C. §§ 3-414(c)-(d), 3-415(d) (2006).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 564 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

II.<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE<br />

A letter of credit is not a negotiable instrument. 7 There are, however,<br />

negotiation credits-credits under which negotiation is permitted.<br />

Although letter of credit practice was originally linked with negotiable<br />

instrument practice, the ties between the two fields of commercial law have become<br />

increasingly attenuated. Under standard international letter of credit practice, with<br />

the exception of acceptances, negotiable drafts or bills of exchange are an<br />

anachronism. The declining status of the draft can best be viewed from the<br />

perspective of the doctrinal evolution of the letter of credit concept of negotiation in<br />

the rules of practice that are applicable to most commercial letters of credit, the<br />

Uniform Customs and Practice for Documentary Credits (hereinafter UCP).'<br />

A. Pre-UCP400 Terminology<br />

Negotiation is a concept that has been with modern letters of credit from the<br />

early twentieth century, the first point in time where LC doctrine can be reliably<br />

tracked. 9 LC undertakings at that time invariably involved a draft that was typically<br />

7. A letter of credit, unlike a negotiable instrument, is a promise to pay that is conditioned on the<br />

timely presentation of complying documents and not an unconditional promise or order to pay. Under the<br />

U.S. Negotiable Instruments <strong>Law</strong>, the predecessor to U.C.C. Article 3, a virtual acceptance was<br />

recognized. BRANNAN'S NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS LAW, § 135 (Frederick K. Beutel ed., W.H.<br />

Anderson, 7th ed. 1948) [hereinafter Negotiable Instruments <strong>Law</strong>] ("[a]n unconditional promise in writing<br />

to accept a bill before it is drawn is deemed an actual acceptance in favor of every person who, upon the<br />

faith thereof, receives the bill for value"). A virtual acceptance was, in effect, a form of letter of credit.<br />

While Lord Mansfield recognized this aspect of negotiation in Pillans v. Van Mierop, (1764) 97 Eng. Rep.<br />

1035 (K.B.), subsequent English cases did not follow his lead.<br />

8. The UCP is promulgated by the Commission on Banking Technique and Practice of the<br />

International Chamber of Commerce headquartered in Paris, France. It articulates standard international<br />

commercial letter of credit practice. The current revision at the time this paper was written, January 2007,<br />

ICC Publication No. 500 (UCP500), became effective January 1994. This version will be replaced July 1<br />

2007 by ICC Publication No. 600, UCP600. Prior versions were issued in 1933 (UCP82), 1951 (UCP151),<br />

1962 (UCP222), 1974 (UCP290), and 1983 (UCP400). Although UCP500 has been translated into virtually<br />

every language in which international commerce is conducted, the official version is in English. See<br />

generally JAMES E. BYRNE, THE COMPARISON OF UCP600 & UCP500 (Institute of International Banking<br />

<strong>Law</strong> & Practice 2007); JAMES E. BYRNE, ISP98 & UCP500 COMPARED (2000): James E. Byrne, Ten Major<br />

Stages in the Evolution of Letter of Credit Practice, DOCUMENTARY CREDIT WORLD, Nov./Dec. 2003, at<br />

28, reprinted in 2004 ANNUAL SURVEY 19; Dan Taylor, The History of the UCP, DOCUMENTARY CREDIT<br />

WORLD, Dec. 1999, at 11, reprinted in 2000 ANNUAL SURVEY 201.<br />

9. Letters of credit are sometimes traced to ancient commerce. These undertakings, however,<br />

differed in important ways from the modern commercial LC. Most importantly, they were general LCs,<br />

that is, there was no named beneficiary. They were addressed to correspondents and requested payment in<br />

favor of the bearer who was a customer of the issuer. They resembled in form and function traveler's<br />

credits or even the modern credit card. The modern LC came into widespread use in post Napoleonic<br />

Wars trade between Europe and North America. These credits were special credits in that they were made<br />

in favor of a named beneficiary in the sense that the obligation to honor ran only to that named person and<br />

no one else. While there are reported LC cases that precede the 1920s, there is little literature and no<br />

serious doctrinal work. Most LC.business was dominated by the London clearing banks and there was<br />

little room for dispute within these networks. When London financial institutions lost their hegemony<br />

during World War I, the purchase of war material was financed by LCs and the banks of neutral countries<br />

or allies handled them through their relatively new export departments. During the War, no presentations<br />

were refused because of the high demand, but after it ended, there were numerous refusals. At that point,<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 565 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

accompanied by documents." While the parties to the underlying transaction were<br />

interested in the documents, the focus of the banker's attention was on the draft that<br />

accompanied them." For a banker, the draft contained his or her instructions. The<br />

banker read the draft as a merchant would read the commercial invoice-as the<br />

compass for the transaction. The draft informed the banker who was to be paid, the<br />

terms of payment expected, the amount, the currency, and who was expected to<br />

make the payment.<br />

At the advent of the modern era, letters of credit required that a draft be drawn<br />

on the issuing bank. An LC contained one of two clauses. Straight credits, in which<br />

the draft was drawn on the issuing bank and could only be presented to the issuing<br />

bank, contained a clause of the following type: "We engage with the beneficiary that<br />

all drafts drawn under and in compliance with the terms of the credit will be duly<br />

honored on delivery of documents as specified if presented at your office on or<br />

before ... 19 . ..12 Where presentation could be made to another bank, the credit<br />

would contain a clause of this type: "We engage with the drawers, endorsers, and<br />

bona fide holders of drafts drawn under and in compliance with the terms of the<br />

credit that the same shall be duly honored on due presentation and delivery of<br />

documents as specified ... if negotiated or presented at ... on or before ... 19 .. ,13<br />

In effect, this latter engagement was understood to render the credit negotiable by<br />

this other bank. Where the bank was instructed to add its confirmation, that bank<br />

effectively engaged to negotiate drafts drawn on the issuer. 4<br />

a number of books were published describing this business and the first attempts at rules of practice were<br />

made. See generally Boris Kozolchyk, Letters of Credit, in 9 INTERNATIONAL ENCYCLOPEDIA OF<br />

COMPARATIVE LAW (Jacob S. Ziegel ed., 2000).<br />

10. However, an LC calling for only the presentation of a draft was and is possible. Credits of this<br />

type are generally referred to as "clean" or colloquially, "suicide" LCs. See INTERNATIONAL STANDBY<br />

PRACTICES (ISP98), ICC Publication No. 590, (1998) Rule 1.10(a)(5); JAMES E. BYRNE, THE OFFICIAL<br />

COMMENTARY ON THE INTERNATIONAL STANDBY PRACTICES 52 (1998) [hereinafter The Official<br />

Commentary].<br />

11. There is a related banking function in which a draft is accompanied by documents, described by<br />

bankers as a collection and by US lawyers as a documentary collection (to distinguish it from a domestic<br />

check collection). There are also ICC Banking Commission Rules that are widely used in connection with<br />

them, the INTERNATIONAL CHAMBER OF COMMERCE, UNIFORM RULES FOR COLLECTIONS, URC 522<br />

(revised 1995). The essential distinction between these two operations is that the bank makes no<br />

undertaking to honor in the case of a collection whereas it does in the case of a letter of credit.<br />

Accordingly, the attitude of the bank towards the documents is quite different. In a collection, the bank<br />

counts the documents to see if the number indicated on the collection letter is present. In a letter of credit<br />

transaction, the bank will examine the documents to determine whether they comply on their face with the<br />

terms and conditions of the letter of credit. Even in a collection, however, the primary role is not accorded<br />

to the draft but to the collection letter. See URC 522 art. 4(a)(1)("All documents sent for collection must<br />

be accompanied by a collection instruction indicating that the collection is subject to URC 522 and giving<br />

complete and precise instructions. Banks are only permitted to act upon the instructions given in such<br />

collection instruction..."). The draft is not a source of instructions. This point is illustrated in a "clean<br />

check collection" in which the document being collected on is a check. In that case, the drawee of the<br />

collection is not the drawee of check but the entity indicated in the collection instructions. See SCADIF,<br />

S.A. v. First Union Nat'l Bank, 344 F.3d 1123, 1129 (11th Cir. 2003) (sustaining the district court's finding<br />

that a bank to whom a "clean check collection" is transmitted is a collecting bank, despite the check's<br />

designation of the bank as a drawee).<br />

12. WILBERT WARD, AMERICAN COMMERCIAL CREDITS 186 (1922).<br />

13. Id. at 187.<br />

14. See UCP600 art. 8(b) (2007) (stating "A confirming bank is irrevocably bound to honour or<br />

negotiate as of the time it adds its confirmation to the credit.) and UCP500 art. 9(b) (1993) (stating "[a]<br />

confirmation of an irrevocable Credit by another bank (the 'Confirming Bank') upon the authorisation or<br />

request of the Issuing Bank, constitutes a definite undertaking of the Confirming Bank, in addition to that<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 566 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

Where the draft was payable at sight, negotiation consisted of paying the<br />

amount due under the letter of credit to the beneficiary after having examined the<br />

documents and concluding that they complied with its terms and conditions." Where<br />

the draft was a time draft, negotiation consisted of paying the amount due under the<br />

letter of credit to the beneficiary discounted to present value after having examined<br />

the documents. Where the bank had issued the credit or added its confirmation, it<br />

negotiated without recourse. 6<br />

B. Post- UCP400 Terminology<br />

The term "nominated" was first introduced in UCP290 (1974) and the concept<br />

of nomination seriously developed in UCP400 (1983)." A nomination entitles the<br />

person nominated to act under the credit and embodies an undertaking by the issuer<br />

and any confirmer to reimburse the nominated bank. The nomination empowers the<br />

nominated bank to act within the scope of the nomination and to undertake any act<br />

not inconsistent with it.<br />

Nomination can effect to whom presentation may be made, the status of the<br />

bank with respect to amendments, the status of the bank with respect to revocable<br />

credits, the status of the bank in the event of claims of fraud on the part of the<br />

beneficiary or forged or fraudulent documents, or the ability of the bank to effect the<br />

transfer of drawing rights, and the entitlement to reimbursement. Nomination of a<br />

bank under an irrevocable credit gives an irrevocable right to a beneficiary to<br />

present documents to that bank for purposes of satisfying the condition that<br />

of the Issuing Bank. . : iv. if the Credit provides for negotiation-to negotiate without recourse to drawers<br />

and/or bona fide holders, Draft(s) drawn by the Beneficiary and/or document(s) presented under the<br />

Credit"). A clause to the same effect appears in all versions of the UCP since 1951.<br />

15. See UCP82 art. 9 (1933) ("[w]hen an irrevocable credit is opened in the form of a Commercial<br />

Letter of Credit, the Letter of Credit itself must include notification of the opening of an irrevocable credit<br />

and constitute the definite engagement by the issuing Bank towards the beneficiary and holder in good<br />

faith to honour all drafts issued by virtue of and in conformity with the clauses and conditions contained in<br />

the document"). While payment at sight originally meant that the document was examined on<br />

presentation and either honored or dishonored, a bank now has time within which to examine documents.<br />

Under UCP500 Article 13(b), it has a reasonable time not to exceed seven banking days. Under UCP600<br />

Article 14(b), it has a maximum of five banking days. See also Seaconsar Far East Ltd. v. Bank Markazi<br />

Jomhouri Islami Iran, (1997) 2 Lloyd's Rep. 89 (Q.B.) (indicating and discussing the original meaning of<br />

'available by sight payment').<br />

16. See UCP151 art. 5 (1951) (stating "[i]n case of credits available by negotiation of drafts, the<br />

confirmation implies only the undertaking of the confirming Bank to negotiate drafts without recourse to<br />

drawer"); UCP500 art. 9(b)(iv) (1993) ("A confirmation of an irrevocable Credit ... constitutes a definite<br />

undertaking ... if the Credit provides for negotiation-to negotiate without recourse to drawers and/or<br />

bona fide holders, Draft(s) drawn by the Beneficiary and/or document(s) presented under the Credit.").<br />

17. The term "nomination" was first introduced in reference to a bank in UCP290(e) (1974) (General<br />

Provisions and Definitions), which spoke of a bank being "authorized to pay or accept under a credit by<br />

being specifically nominated in the credit" or being "authorized to negotiate under a credit either i. by<br />

being specifically nominated in the credit, or ii. by the credit being freely negotiable by any bank." These<br />

references were developed in UCP400 (1983), which introduced and defined the term "Nominated Bank"<br />

in Article 11(b): "All credits must nominate the bank (nominated bank) which is authorized to pay<br />

(paying bank), or to accept drafts (accepting bank), or to negotiate (negotiating bank), unless the credit<br />

allows negotiation by any bank (negotiating bank)." The name was used more extensively in UCP500<br />

(1993) and is used throughout UCP600 (2007), which contains an article 12 entitled "Nomination" in<br />

addition to a definition of the term in article 2.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 567 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

documents be timely presented prior to the expiration of the letter of credit whether<br />

or not it takes up its nomination. A nominated bank is not obligated to act by virtue<br />

of being nominated and may elect not to do so. With the exception of a confirming<br />

bank, a nominated bank does not make any engagement by advising the credit or by<br />

receiving a presentation, examining the credit, or forwarding it to the confirmer or<br />

issuer unless it expressly so indicates.' 8<br />

Instead of distinguishing only between straight and circular (undertakings that<br />

were meant to circulate) as did earlier UCP versions, by UCP400 (1983) it was<br />

recognized that a bank could be nominated to confirm (confirming bank), pay<br />

(paying bank), 9 or negotiate (negotiating bank).<br />

These categories tended to overlap. Negotiation did not necessarily entail<br />

nomination and could be undertaken by the issuing bank which had engaged itself<br />

under its letter of credit. Nor was it confined to a negotiating bank since a<br />

confirming bank could make an undertaking to negotiate as well. Although not<br />

always fully grasped even by LC bankers, negotiation in post UCP400 LC practice<br />

encompasses two quite different functions. On the one hand, it represents a type of<br />

undertaking given by either an issuing or confirming bank to negotiate drafts drawn<br />

on either the applicant 0 or issuer respectively and the fulfillment or honor of that<br />

18. See UCP600 art. 12(a) (noting that "[ulniess a nominated bank is the confirming bank, an<br />

authorization to honour or negotiate does not impose any obligation on that nominated bank to honour or<br />

negotiate, except when expressly agreed to by that nominated bank and so communicated to the<br />

beneficiary"); id. 12(c) (stating "[rieceipt or examination and forwarding of documents by a nominated<br />

bank that is not a confirming bank does not make that nominated bank liable to honour or negotiate, nor<br />

does it constitute honour or negotiation").<br />

19. The UCP has never systematically addressed the role of the paying bank. Neither a paying bank<br />

nor a negotiating bank make an undertaking to honor but if the paying bank acts, it is to pay as opposed to<br />

negotiate. When drafts are used, the draft would be drawn on a paying bank. As the drawee, its payment<br />

would be final since payment by the drawee would extinguish the draft without there being any right of<br />

recourse. On the other hand, the draft would be endorsed to the negotiatingbank and any negotiation by<br />

it would not be final unless it disclaimed its right to-recourse or the indorsement to it was without recourse.<br />

The UCP has always referred to the role of a paying bank however obscurely. UCP82 (1933) Article 10<br />

links a paying bank with the negotiating bank with respect to notice of refusal. Similar oblique references<br />

to the paying bank occur in UCP151 (1951) Article 43 (right to refuse presentation if unduly delayed),<br />

Article 49 (Transfer); UCP222 (1962) Articles 41 (same as UCP151 Article 43), Article 46 (Transfer);<br />

UCP290 (1974) Articles 13 (Reimbursement), 46 (Transfer); UCP400 (1983) Articles 11 (Nominated<br />

Banks) (which contains a parenthetical definition of the term), 21(a) & (c) (Reimbursement), 54(f)<br />

(Transfer); UCP500 Article 19 (Bank-to-Bank Reimbursement Arrangements). In addition, there have<br />

been regular references to payment (as opposed to negotiation) by a bank which have been understood to<br />

refer to a nominated bank other than the confirming bank. UCP600 has deleted express reference to a<br />

paying bank although it contains what might be regarded as oblique references to it. UCP600 (2007)<br />

Article 2 (Definitions) paragraph 11 "Negotiation" excludes banks on whom a draft is drawn which would<br />

include paying banks where the credit called for a draft drawn on the paying bank. UCP600 Article 12(a)<br />

(Nomination) refers to an authorization to pay in a context that makes it apparent that it is referring to a<br />

bank other than the confirming bank. Likewise, UCP600 Article 8(i)(b) can be read to refer to such a<br />

bank (although it could also encompass another confirming bank whom the confirmer was required to<br />

reimburse).<br />

20. A credit could provide for a draft drawn on an applicant in which case the issuer and any<br />

confirmer would undertake to negotiate without recourse. The consequences of expecting the applicant to<br />

accept or otherwise honor such a draft were not fully addressed in the UCP and concern about drafts<br />

drawn on the applicant arose as a result of claims made by some banks that they were not liable as an<br />

issuer where the draft was drawn on the applicant or accepted by the applicant. The ICC Banking<br />

Commission rejected this position but the concern lingered. See CHARLES DEL BUSTO, UCP 500 & 400<br />

COMPARED 23 (1993) (References to drafts on the applicant that "or payment will be made" in UCP400<br />

Articles 10(a)(i) and 10(a)(ii) were deleted because they "defined a less certain and less reliable promise<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 568 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

undertaking." On the other hand, negotiation also consists of a nomination by the<br />

issuing bank of a bank that is authorized to negotiate drafts drawn under the credit<br />

but is not requested or authorized to add its own undertaking to the beneficiary.<br />

Such a nominated bank is characterized as a "negotiating bank" in LC practice.<br />

Although some writers and a few courts have confused the notion of nomination and<br />

negotiation with the doctrine of agency, agency is inapt to describe either. 22 While<br />

this designation is somewhat illogical since both issuers and confirmers can also<br />

negotiate when they so undertake and could have been described as negotiating<br />

banks, it serves to reinforce the distinction between a bank that is obligated on the<br />

LC and one that is not. Where a negotiating bank is involved, the drafts can be<br />

drawn on a paying bank, the confirming bank, the issuer, the applicant, or a third<br />

person but not the negotiating bank. 23<br />

than the Issuing Bank or Confirming Bank's irrevocable promise and primary liability 'to pay.' . . . A<br />

Beneficiary attempting to rely on such an undefined promise did not know who the primarily liable payor<br />

was, or when the bank's liability to pay was enforceable."). See also THE INTERNATIONAL CHAMBER OF<br />

COMMERCE, OPINIONS OF THE ICC BANKING COMMISSION 1995-1996, ICC Publication No. 565, Resp.<br />

205, at 25 (Gary Collyer ed., 1997). As is typical with UCP drafting, it addressed the issue obliquely and did<br />

not make an outright statement of the liability of the issuer or confirmer notwithstanding the draft being<br />

drawn on the applicant. UCP600 (2007) Article 6(c) (Availability, Expiry Date and Place for Presentation)<br />

turns this approach around. It states that "[a] credit must not be issued available by a draft drawn on the<br />

applicant." The UCP600 prohibition is stronger than the statement of UCP500 but, since the UCP is<br />

variable, a term in the credit requiring the presentation of a draft drawn on the applicant would expressly<br />

vary UCP600 Article 6(c). Where it is varied, the absence of direction regarding the impact of such a draft<br />

is regrettable, but is not fatal since it is apparent that the draft is peripheral to the issuer or confirmer's<br />

obligation. In that sense, it is just another document and should be so treated notwithstanding the silence<br />

of UCP600 on this point. Interestingly, where a bank issues a credit for its own account as permitted under<br />

UCP600 Article 2 (Definitions) paragraph 10 ("Issuing Bank"), a draft drawn on it is in effect dawn on the<br />

applicant. In such a situation, the draft would also be treated as a bank document.<br />

21. See UCP600 art. 2 para. 9 (artificially excluding negotiation from the meaning of "honour"). The<br />

ordinary sense of the term "honour" is the fulfillment of an undertaking which, in the case of an issuer or<br />

confirmer, would included an undertaking to negotiate.<br />

22. How can there be an agency relationship where the supposed "agent" cannot bind the principal?<br />

A negotiating bank has no ability under the UCP or international letter of credit practice to bind the<br />

issuing bank. Whether or not it acts is within its sole discretion. If it does so, it is able to do so with or<br />

without recourse against the beneficiary in the event that it has erred with respect to the compliance of the<br />

documents and with respect to issuer solvency or country risk. It can make its decision as to whether to act<br />

after it has examined the documents and, until it elects to act, is not bound by any time limits. While its<br />

right to be reimbursed may be affected if the documents do not comply, it has no duties to the issuing bank.<br />

See JAMES G. BARNES. JAMES E. BYRNE, & AMELIA H. Boss, THE ABCS OF UCC ARTICLE 5: LETrERS<br />

OF CREDIT 45 (1998) ("Nominated persons are best viewed as independent contractors whose various roles<br />

are defined by LC practice.... They may be viewed as agents for the issuer or as agents for beneficiaries or<br />

both, but application of agency law will often as not lead to the wrong conclusion. Nominated persons have<br />

little or no right to bind issuers or beneficiaries" ). See also RICHARD KING, GUTTERIDGE AND<br />

MEGRAH'S THE LAW OF BANKERS' COMMERCIAL CREDITS 106 (8th ed. 2001) ("A negotiating bank<br />

negotiates on the invitation contained in the credit and not as an agent..."); JOHN F. DOLAN, THE LAW<br />

OF LETTrERS OF CREDIT, para. 8.02[6] n.59 (2003) (noting "[tihat is not to say that the negotiating bank is<br />

an agent of the issuer."); Bank of N.S. v. Angelica-Whitewear Ltd., [2003] 1 S.C.R. 59, 86-87 (suggesting<br />

that the negotiating bank acts for itself, but it does so with the understanding that the issuer's undertaking<br />

runs to the negotiating bank and not just to the beneficiary").<br />

23. There is another sense in which the term negotiation is used in letter of credit practice-the<br />

payment of any undertaking involving another bank. This use derives from the pre-UCP400 distinction<br />

between straight and circular credits. It is a use which has been officially discouraged. See ICC BANKING<br />

COMMISSION, UCP1974/1983 REVISIONS COMPARED AND EXPLAINED 12 (1984). Nonetheless, it still<br />

surfaces in the casual vocabulary of bankers because it offers a shorthand means of capturing the concept<br />

of reimbursement.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 569 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

Following the format of SWIFT MT700 messages, UCP600 distinguishes<br />

between the notions of "Available With. . ." and "Available By .. . A credit is<br />

"available with" the issuer, or a nominated bank which can include a negotiating<br />

bank. It can be "available by" payment, deferred payment, acceptance, or<br />

negotiation. Where the credit is "available by" negotiation, the bank it is "available<br />

with" the negotiating bank.<br />

III. ISSUES REGARDING NEGOTIATION OF LCs<br />

Under modern letter of credit practice and law, there are several issues which<br />

dominate the concept of negotiation and which, to an extent, mark the difference<br />

between negotiation under negotiable instrument law and under letter of credit<br />

practice and law. They are a. the requirement of a draft; b. formality requirements<br />

for a draft; c. who negotiates; d. how negotiation occurs; e. recourse; and f.<br />

protection of banks that negotiate in the event of letter of credit fraud. These issues<br />

overlap and, for clarity, there is some redundancy in explaining them.<br />

A. The Requirement of a Draft<br />

Under negotiable instrument law and practice, there must be a negotiable<br />

instrument (for our purposes, a draft) in order for negotiation to occur.<br />

In its evolution, letter of credit practice has deviated considerably from its<br />

original focus on the draft (to pay it or to accept it or to reimburse another bank<br />

who accepted or negotiated it) whether or not there was "negotiation." The early<br />

unwritten expectation that a draft would always be presented under an LC no longer<br />

obtains. With the exception of credits that contain an undertaking to accept, it is not<br />

uncommon for UCP commercial credits to dispense with the requirement of a draft.<br />

For standbys, a draft is unnecessary and irrelevant. Even with respect to an<br />

acceptance, the role of the draft has been supplanted by the deferred payment<br />

undertaking in which an obligation to pay over time is incurred under the terms of<br />

the credit. Properly understood, this undertaking is the functional equivalent of a<br />

acceptance.2<br />

24. See UCP600 art. 6(a)-(b) ("A credit must state the bank with which it is available or whether it is<br />

available with any bank. A credit available with a nominated bank is also available with the issuing bank..<br />

• . A credit must state whether it is available by sight payment, deferred payment, acceptance or<br />

negotiation."). This data is contained in SWIFT MT700 Field 41a (Available With ... By ... ) which is a<br />

mandatory field.<br />

25. The deferred payment undertaking was first recognized in UCP400 (1983) article 10(a)(ii). Its<br />

emergence was noted in ROLF EBERTH & E.P. ELLINGER, Deferred Payment Credits: A Comparative<br />

Analysis of Their Special Problems, 14 J. MAR. L. & CoM. 387, 390-91 (1983). It emerged in Post World<br />

War II commerce to avoid stamp taxes or limitations on the term of finance imposed on drafts by central<br />

banks. Because the ICC Banking Commission never fully addressed the implications of the deferred<br />

payment undertaking, the questions of the right to an acknowledgment by the beneficiary of the obligation<br />

incurred and the implications of beneficiary LC fraud were not expressly addressed in the UCP. They<br />

were answered comprehensively in U.C.C. § 5-109(a) (Fraud and Forgery) (2006), which provided that<br />

[i]f a presentation is made that appears on its face strictly to comply with the terms and<br />

conditions of the letter of credit, but a required document is forged or materially fraudulent, or<br />

honor of the presentation would facilitate a material fraud by the beneficiary on the issuer or<br />

applicant: (1) the issuer shall honor the presentation, if honor is demanded by (i) a nominated<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 570 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

Most importantly for this analysis, a draft is not even required under LC<br />

practice, where the LC contains an undertaking to negotiate or authorizes a<br />

nominated bank to negotiate. LC negotiation can be against the documents<br />

themselves without there being a draft at all. 2 ' UCP600 (2007) Article 2<br />

(Definitions) paragraph 2 states that "Negotiation" can be of "drafts (drawn on a<br />

bank other than the nominated bank) and/or documents."<br />

Even where a letter of credit requires a draft, its role is diminished. Under<br />

modern LC practice, a simple demand can suffice to indicate the tenor of the<br />

drawing. Moreover a draft is for the bank's internal records and banks retain them<br />

and do not regularly forward them to the applicant and, as will be discussed, there is<br />

some confusion about the status of a draft when it is required by the credit.<br />

person who has given value in good faith and without notice of forgery or material fraud, (ii) a<br />

confirmer who has honored its confirmation in good faith, (iii) a holder in due course of a draft<br />

drawn under the letter of credit which was taken after acceptance by the issuer or nominated<br />

person, or (iv) an assignee of the issuer's or nominated person's deferred obligation that was<br />

taken for value and without notice of forgery or material fraud after the obligation was<br />

incurred by the issuer or nominated person; and (2) the issuer, acting in good faith, may honor<br />

or dishonor the presentation in any other case.<br />

The problem forecast by Eberth and Ellinger surfaced in a series of cases in the 1990s starting with Banco<br />

Santander S.A. v. Bayfern Ltd. & Ors., [1999] 2 All E.R. (Comm.) (O.B.) 18, aff d, Banco Santander SA v.<br />

Banque Paribas, [2000] 1 All E.R. (Comm.) (C.A.) 776, in which the courts ruled that a confirmer that<br />

discounted its own deferred payment undertaking was not entitled to reimbursement where they was<br />

supervening LC fraud by the beneficiary before the maturity of the obligation. The English court in Banco<br />

Santander noted the absence of direction in the UCP. That direction has been provided by UCP600<br />

Article 7(c) (Issuing Bank Undertaking), 8(c) (Confirming Bank Undertaking), and 12(b) (Nomination).<br />

UCP600 Article 7(c) provides that<br />

[a]n issuing bank undertakes to reimburse a nominated bank that has honoured or negotiated a<br />

complying presentation and forwarded the documents to the issuing bank. Reimbursement for<br />

the amount of a complying presentation under a credit available by acceptance or deferred<br />

payment is due at maturity, whether or not the nominated bank prepaid or purchased before<br />

maturity. An issuing bank's undertaking to reimburse a nominated bank is independent of the<br />

issuing bank's undertaking to the beneficiary.<br />

26. The notion of negotiation of documents without drafts is not new. There is an ambiguous<br />

reference in UCP82 (1933) Article 45 that may indicate the early recognition of the negotiation of<br />

documents without drafts. It stated an extension of the deadline for shipment also extends the time "for<br />

presentation or negotiation of documents or drafts." The reference is not unambiguous as the words<br />

presentation/documents and negotiation/drafts could be in parallel instead of meaning that both<br />

"documents and drafts" could be subject to "presentation and negotiation." This provision is continued in<br />

similar form in UCPI51 (1951) Article 45. However, UCP290 (1974) Article 8(b) and UCP400 (1983)<br />

Article 16(a) speak of "[p]ayment, acceptance, or negotiation against documents." By this point, it is clear<br />

that the letter of credit community recognized that a draft was not necessary for letter of credit negotiation.<br />

UCP500 (1993) Article 9(a)(iv) defines negotiation as involving "Draft(s) drawn by the Beneficiary and/or<br />

document(s) presented under the Credit." UCP600 (2007) continues to recognize negotiation of<br />

documents without drafts in Article 2 (Definitions) paragraph 11 "Negotiation" which provides in part that<br />

it "means the purchase by the nominated bank of drafts and/or documents. ... To some extent, this<br />

practice can be said to have evolved from the requirement of a demand in lieu of draft but it readily came<br />

to be recognized that the demand could be fictionalized from the presentation of documents which was<br />

deemed to constitute a demand.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 571 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

B. Formality Requirements<br />

While there may be greater or lesser degrees of rigidity in the formal<br />

requirements for an undertaking to be a negotiable instrument under the various<br />

statutes or codes, each sets forth its own requirements with clarity and there is little<br />

doubt as to the necessary elements. 2 " The codes commonly require a signed writing,<br />

a promise to pay that is not conditioned on any event or term not stated in the<br />

undertaking, words of negotiability usually in an accepted formulation, a certain<br />

amount, and no other promise or obligation that affects these undertakings. There<br />

can be other requirements, but there are also default rules that imply some of these<br />

provisions, and there are often provisions that address various issues such as<br />

interest. 28<br />

Since the UCP does not address the contents of drafts, one might conclude that<br />

there are no LC formality requirements for a draft. 9 That conclusion is not correct<br />

for commercial letters of credit. There are requirements that are intermittently<br />

applied to drafts but they are not necessarily the requirements of negotiable<br />

instruments law. Some of these requirements are reflected in the International<br />

Standard Banking Practices (ISBP 2003) which are formal interpretations of<br />

UCP500 issued by the ICC Banking Commission. 30<br />

Unlike negotiable instrument law which implies a tenor, ISBP paragraph 45<br />

(Tenor) requires that the tenor of the draft correspond with that of the credit. 3 '<br />

27. See generally ELLINGER, supra note 2, §§ 279-310.<br />

28. See, e.g., U.C.C. § 2-104(a)(2) (2006) (requiring that a negotiable instrument be on demand or for<br />

a definite time). On the other hand, it implies that the instrument is a demand instrument when it is silent.<br />

Therefore, this rule is only applicable where it is apparent on its face that the instrument is neither for<br />

demand nor for a definite time. An issue that has been recently of considerable interest is the use of an<br />

outside source such as a published rate provided that it is readily determinable. See U.C.C. § 3-112(b)<br />

(permitting reference to an objective source outside the "four corners" of the instrument for interest<br />

provided that it is objectively determinable).<br />

29. Banking practice is, in fact, of two minds about whether or not the draft, if required, is to be<br />

regarded as a "document" to be presented under the letter of credit. The distinction surfaced in UCP500<br />

Article 9(a)(iv) (Liability of Issuing and Confirming Banks) in addressing problems raised by LCs<br />

requiring documents drawn on the applicant or another entity other than the issuer or a nominated bank.<br />

It provides, in part, that "[i]f the Credit nevertheless calls for Draft(s) on the Applicant, banks will consider<br />

such Draft(s) as an additional document(s)." This verbiage is intended to signify that the issuer remains<br />

obligated under the LC, regardless of the draft. The implication is that in other credits, the draft is not just<br />

"another document." This notion, however, has little impact on the examination of the draft. For<br />

purposes of determining compliance of a required draft, the draft is to be examined as if it were another<br />

document. The real question is not whether it is to be examined but by what standard.<br />

30. At its May 2000 meeting, the Commission on Banking Technique and Practice of the International<br />

Chamber of Commerce (ICC Banking Commission) established a task force to document international<br />

standard banking practice for the examination of documents presented under documentary credits issued<br />

subject to the UCP. See ICC BANKING COMMISSION, INTERNATIONAL STANDARD BANKING PRACTICE<br />

FOR THE EXAMINATION OF DOCUMENTS UNDER DOCUMENTARY CREDITS 3 (2003) [hereinafter ISBP<br />

(2003)] (describing how the ISBP complements the UCP500 by filling in gaps and explaining the practices<br />

that underline UCP500). The ISBP is a statement of the "standard banking practice" referenced in<br />

UCP500 Article 13(a), sentence 2. The ISBP is based on ICC Banking Commission Opinions and<br />

Decisions and its understanding of the practices reflected in them. Revisions, finalized at the Spring 2007<br />

ICC Banking Commission <strong>Meeting</strong>, have been made to the ISBP to align it with and make it applicable to<br />

UCP600 [hereinafter ISBP (2007)].<br />

31. There is no indication in the ISBP as to whether a credit that requires presentation of a sight draft<br />

would be satisfied by a draft that requires payment without stating that it is drawn at sight. Since the<br />

default rule would make such a draft payable at sight, it should be regarded as complying with such an LC<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 572 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

ISBP paragraph 45(a) also requires that, except for a sight draft, it be possible "to<br />

establish the maturity date from the data in the draft itself" '32 and other<br />

subparagraphs and paragraphs provide detailed rules for calculation of the time.<br />

Thus, where the LC requires that the tenor of the draft be "30 days from B/L date,"<br />

LC practice as reflected in the ISBP would require that the B/L date or the maturity<br />

date be stated in the draft in order to provide a basis for calculation since it would be<br />

necessary to look to the bill of lading (even if it was presented in tandem with the<br />

draft) to ascertain the date if it was not stated in the draft. This approach leads to<br />

the somewhat odd result that a draft that literally replicated the terms of the LC<br />

(draft drawn "30 days for bill of lading date" under an LC with precisely that<br />

requirement) would be regarded as non complying."<br />

This result is consistent with traditional negotiable instrument law. Although<br />

negotiable instrument law focuses on the draft itself, letter of credit practice need<br />

not do so since there are other documents that accompany the draft, namely the bill<br />

of lading which would enable the bank to make the calculation. This rule is<br />

particularly bizarre where the draft is not negotiated or accepted. Despite the rigid<br />

rule, where a draft is presented that does not contain the date from which the<br />

calculation of maturity is to take place, many banks to whom the documents are<br />

presented do such a calculation and note it on the draft. Such a practice should be<br />

given effect and not regarded as an alteration of the draft.<br />

ISBP paragraphs 52 and 53, 54 and 55, respectively, also require that drafts<br />

drawn under UCP500 letters of credit contain an amount reflecting the amount<br />

drawn under the LC, be drawn on the party stated in the LC, and be drawn by the<br />

beneficiary."<br />

As to the other requirements of local law regarding the formality requirements<br />

for a draft, banking practice is largely silent. There is, however, one additional<br />

respect in which a LC banker would probably require compliance, namely the<br />

presence of the "magic words" of negotiability, namely "order" or "bearer."<br />

Although this requirement is not reflected in the UCP or ISBP, the presence or<br />

absence of the words "or order" is arguably the only technical indicium of<br />

term.<br />

32. ISBP (2003), supra note 30, para. 45(a) (stating that "[i]f a draft is drawn at a tenor other than<br />

sight, or other than a certain period after sight, it must be possible to establish the maturity date from the<br />

data in the draft itself."). ISBP (2007), supra note 30, para. 43(a) is identical.<br />

33. This result is not only ironic in light of certain rigid interpretations of the strict compliance rule<br />

since there is a literal replication of the terms of the credit. It is unfortunate that the drafters did not<br />

structure an alternative in this situation, either permitting the banker to insert the date on the draft or<br />

permitting the bank to calculate it on the basis of the attached bill of lading. As long as the tenor is<br />

correctly calculated, the applicant should not be permitted to refuse documents because of the failure to<br />

reflect the actual date of the bill of lading in the way that the draft is drawn. For that reason, neither<br />

should the issuer since it is able to make the necessary calculation. As to the ability of anyone else to make<br />

the calculation, they can decide whether or not to purchase the draft. If they were to decide not to do so, it<br />

is the beneficiary whose options are reduced, but there is no impact on the issuer or applicant.<br />

34. See ISBP (2003), supra note 30, paras. 52-55 (stating that (52) "[t]he amount in words must<br />

accurately reflect the amount in figures if both are shown, and indicate the currency, as stated in the<br />

credit"; that (53) "[tlhe amount must agree with that of the invoice, unless otherwise stated in the credit or<br />

as a result of UCP sub-Article 37(b)" that (54) "[t]he draft must be drawn on the party stated in the<br />

credit"; and that (55) "[t]he draft must be drawn by the beneficiary"). These practices appear as ISBP<br />

(2007), supra note 30, paras. 50-53.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 573 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

negotiability (other than the correspondence of obvious data regarding parties, the<br />

tenor, and the amount with the terms of the LC) that registers with bankers. 35<br />

Where a court concludes that the requirement of a draft on an LC means a<br />

draft that meets the requirements of local law, the question of which law arises.<br />

While there are similarities under various legal regimes and while LC bankers<br />

usually do not insist on the specifics where they disagree, there are some issues that<br />

can impact the question of whether a draft is adequate under local law. Two that<br />

have arisen are the language in which the draft is written and whether there are<br />

corrections.<br />

Where the LC requires that all documents be written in English, a court has<br />

concluded that a required draft may be in French, where mandated by the law<br />

governing the beneficiary (who draws the draft). 36 While standard international<br />

letter of credit practice permits corrections or alterations to drafts provided that they<br />

are authenticated, the laws of some countries do not permit corrections or<br />

alterations to drafts. 37<br />

Whether the risk of the application of local law is to rest on the applicant,<br />

intermediary banks, or the beneficiary is not altogether clear. Absent a special<br />

requirement otherwise, it would seem that a beneficiary would be entitled to draw a<br />

draft in accordance with its own law and that doing so would not constitute a<br />

discrepancy. Had the applicant required another form, it should have so specified in<br />

the LC. It is clear that where a bank honors the presentation of such a draft, it is<br />

entitled to reimbursement since the UCP provides that the applicant bears the risk<br />

of the application of local law. 3 "<br />

The reality, however, is that the use of a legally negotiable instrument only<br />

matters in the discrete situation where there is to be acceptance financing.<br />

Accordingly, there are some cases that have recognized that a draft is simply an<br />

order to pay and concluded that such an order may be inferred from any demand to<br />

pay. 39 Absent these situations, there is little, if any, difference between a demand-a<br />

draft that does not qualify under applicable law as a negotiable instrument-and a<br />

draft that does so qualify. Indeed, it is possible to infer a demand from a<br />

presentation of documents.<br />

ISP98, the rules of practice for standby letters of credit, takes this approach to<br />

drafts. It provides that a required demand need not be separate from other<br />

documents presented, and, if a separate demand is required, it need not be in the<br />

35. Although, given banker's mania for having everything dated, see ISBP (2003) paras. 13-19 and<br />

ISBP (2007) paras. 13-18, the absence of a date may also register with them although at least some legal<br />

systems would imply that the date of the draft was the date on which it was issued.<br />

36. Credit Industriel et Commercial v. China Merchants Bank, (2002) 2 All E.R. (Comm.) 427,436-37<br />

(Q.B.).<br />

37. See ISBP (2003), supra note 30, para. 58 (warning that "[in some countries draft(s) showing<br />

corrections and alterations are not acceptable even with the drawer's authentication. Issuing Banks in such<br />

countries should make a statement in the credit to the effect that no correction or alteration must appear in<br />

the drafts(s)"). This practice appears as ISBP (2007), supra note 30, para. 56.<br />

38. See UCP600 art. 37(d) (2007) (stating that "[tihe applicant shall be bound by and liable to<br />

indemnify a bank against all obligations and responsibilities imposed by foreign laws and usages").<br />

39. See, e.g., All Am. Semiconductor, Inc. v. Wells Fargo Bank Minnesota, N.A., 105 Fed.Appx. 886<br />

(8th Cir. 2004) af.d Civ. No. 01-1441, 2003 WL 22455502 (D. Minn. filed Jan. 3, 2003).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 574 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

form of a draft unless the standby expressly so requires, in which case, the required<br />

"draft" "need not be in negotiable form ...."'<br />

It is also unclear whether and to what extent an issuer can waive requirements<br />

about a draft or even presentation of a draft itself and retain its right to<br />

reimbursement. Since the draft is rarely, if ever, required by the applicant, and is<br />

retained by the issuer-except where it is drawn on the applicant-any objection to a<br />

defective draft by the applicant would be seizing on a fortuitous circumstance to<br />

avoid its obligation to reimburse.<br />

Where it is required, then, the position of the draft in LC practice is curious at<br />

best and ambiguous at worst.<br />

C. Who Negotiates?<br />

Under the law applicable to negotiable instruments, any entity to whom a draft<br />

is issued or indorsed and delivered, or who is in possession of it if it is in bearer form,<br />

can negotiate it. There need be no special designation or nomination of a person for<br />

it to do so. Generally speaking, this person is the transferor or negotiator.<br />

Under LC practice, however, it is only the bank that is nominated to do so (and<br />

not the beneficiary/drawer) that is said to negotiate. Absent nomination, there can<br />

be no LC negotiation of a draft.<br />

Where a bank is not nominated in the letter of credit to negotiate, negotiation<br />

does not occur even if the draft is in fact made payable to the beneficiary's order and<br />

legally negotiated (in the negotiable-instruments sense) to a non-nominated<br />

(collecting bank). In effect, in LC practice and law, negotiation is limited to banks so<br />

nominated. Negotiation of a draft under negotiable instrument law does not<br />

constitute LC negotiation unless the transferee is a nominated bank.<br />

D. How Does Negotiation Occur?<br />

Under negotiable instruments law, a negotiable instrument is negotiated by<br />

indorsement by the transferor and delivery if it is issued or indorsed to the order of a<br />

named entity or, if in bearer form, by delivery alone. Negotiation is a special form of<br />

transfer by which the rights inherent in the instrument are transferred in such a way<br />

that the transferee becomes a holder who is entitled to exercise them. A mere<br />

assignment of the instrument does not achieve this effect, although an assignee is<br />

able to succeed and exercise certain rights to the instrument of the assignor and<br />

indirectly shelter under the status of one to whom the instrument has been<br />

negotiated.<br />

The negotiation of a draft drawn under a letter of credit in accordance with the<br />

law of negotiable instruments not only is not LC negotiation, but it has no effect<br />

whatsoever with respect to rights under the LC. If the beneficiary of an LC draws a<br />

40. ISP98, supra note 10, Rule 4.16(c) (Demand for Payment) (stating that "[a] demand may be in the<br />

form of a draft or other instruction, order, or request to pay. If a standby requires presentation of a 'draft'<br />

or 'bill of exchange,' that draft or bill of exchange need not be in negotiable form unless the standby so<br />

states.").<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 575 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

draft in accordance with the terms of the LC, makes the draft payable to itself, and<br />

indorses and delivers it to a person or entity not nominated in the LC as a<br />

negotiating bank, there has been negotiation under the law of negotiable<br />

instruments, but no negotiation under LC practice or law.<br />

In effect, LC negotiation starts at the other end, with the transferee.<br />

Negotiation under a letter of credit takes place when a nominated negotiating bank<br />

purchases the presentation (which need not include a draft) under a letter of credit.<br />

The nature of the exchange is linked to the meaning of LC negotiation and is<br />

addressed later in this paper. It is clear, however, that something more than the<br />

physical transfer of a draft with necessary indorsements is involved in LC<br />

negotiation.<br />

Indeed, indorsement is almost irrelevant to LC negotiation. Of course, where<br />

there is no draft, it is without meaning. Even where there is a draft, as indicated, LC<br />

practice hardly pays attention to it. There is no provision in the UCP regarding<br />

indorsement of a draft. Nor does the UCP indicate to whom the draft must be made<br />

payable, and it is rare for the LC to so specify. The general expectation is that a<br />

draft will be made payable to the order of the beneficiary or to its bank. 41<br />

Where the draft is payable to the named beneficiary, it is usually endorsed in<br />

blank, but credits requiring indorsement of a draft are virtually unknown, and no<br />

reported cases have been found in which dishonor of a credit was based on the<br />

absence of a necessary indorsement on a draft.<br />

When documents are forwarded, it is not uncommon for the issuer or<br />

confirming bank to demand that a nominated bank add its indorsement to the draft.<br />

Where the draft is indorsed in blank by the beneficiary, there is no basis for such a<br />

requirement in the UCP in letter of credit practice or in the law of negotiable<br />

instruments. The desire for such an indorsement is probably driven by the thought<br />

that it yields an additional right against the bank outside of letter of credit law and<br />

practice. The value of any such right, however, is tied up with the right of recourse,<br />

which is discussed in the next section.<br />

While addressing the issue obliquely, the drafters of the ISBP effectively<br />

ducked it. ISBP (2003) paragraph 51 provides that "[t]he draft must be endorsed, if<br />

necessary." It is unfortunate that the ISBP did not make it clear that refusal to<br />

honor or pay without adding an indorsement where the documents otherwise comply<br />

constitutes wrongful refusal, unless the letter of credit expressly requires that the<br />

draft contain the indorsement of the negotiating bank 2<br />

41. Where a draft accompanying documents is not payable to the named beneficiary or the bank<br />

processing the presentations, the concern is not with respect to negotiation, but rather that an indirect<br />

assignment of proceeds is taking place without paying required fees and adding to the risk of the bank that<br />

pays who is expected to pay the named beneficiary. While this point has not been tested, many banks<br />

would refuse to pay the LC proceeds to anyone but the named beneficiary or transferee absent an<br />

assignment of proceeds. See ISP98, supra note 10, Rule 4.13(b) (No Responsibility to Identify<br />

Beneficiary).<br />

42. The parallel provision of ISBP (2007) is para. 49. The ISBP should have provided that "unless the<br />

credit requires otherwise, no indorsement of a draft by a negotiating bank may be required unless the draft<br />

is issued to the order of the negotiating bank or indorsed to it or its order. In that case, the negotiating<br />

bank may indorse the draft without recourse."<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 576 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

E. Recourse<br />

Where a draft presented under an LC is drawn on the issuer and the issuer<br />

refuses to honor or where it is drawn on the applicant and the applicant refuses to<br />

honor, questions arise concerning the ability of a bank that has negotiated it to<br />

obtain recourse against prior indorsers and the drawer.<br />

Under negotiable instruments law, the notion of recourse relates to the<br />

obligations that arise from signing an instrument. It signifies a right arising from the<br />

issuance or transfer of the instrument by indorsement that enables a transferee to<br />

recover from the transferor based on the transferor's obligation on the instrument<br />

itself that arises from signing it in the event that the instrument is dishonored or<br />

unpaid when it is due. 43 Recourse on a negotiable instrument operates unless<br />

affirmatively disclaimed" or, under some systems, the obligation of a person signing<br />

is discharged by an acceptance or by the failure to give any necessary notice or some<br />

other action. 45<br />

While recourse is mentioned in the UCP, the rules have never coherently<br />

addressed it-possibly for the same reasons that they have not addressed issues<br />

relating to drafts. Under letter of credit law and practice, recourse means the ability<br />

to reclaim the proceeds paid under a letter of credit presentation. There are<br />

significant differences between recourse under a LC and a negotiable instrument.<br />

In the first place, it operates with respect to LCs regardless of whether or not<br />

there is a draft.<br />

In the second place, under letter of credit practice and law, recourse against the<br />

beneficiary is not available to an issuer or confirmer regardless of whether or not<br />

there is an express disclaimer. While the unavailability of recourse for issuing and<br />

43. There may be other parallel theories of liability that are functionally similar, but that do not arise<br />

from obligations on the instrument. U.S. law, for example, posits warranties (a curiosity of the common<br />

law) that arise as a result of transfer and presentment that are not directly affected by whether or not one<br />

has indorsed. Under U.C.C. section 3-416(a) (2006), for example, a transfer warranty arises whether or not<br />

there is indorsement, but, if the transfer does not include an indorsement, only runs to the immediate<br />

transferee. An indorsement disclaiming liability on the indorsement ("without recourse") does not affect<br />

or otherwise limit warranties.<br />

44. ELLINGER, supra note 2, section 373 notes that the right of recourse must be be "'negatived' (viz.<br />

Excluded)" under section 16(a) of the U.K. Bills of Exchange Act, 1882, 45 & 46 Vict. c. 61.<br />

45. By signing a draft, an entity assumed liability on it unless disclaimed. The nature of the liability<br />

depended on the manner in which it was signed, whether as drawer, acceptor, or indorser. Under local<br />

negotiable instruments law, there were certain conditions to each type of liability. For example, the<br />

obligation of an indorser is typically conditioned on presentation of the draft and any necessary notice of<br />

dishonor. Under civil law, formal protest is necessary, Geneva Convention, supra note 2, Articles 44, 46,<br />

whereas it is necessary under the U.K. Bills of Exchange Act sections 4(1) and 51(1)-(2) only for a foreign<br />

bill and not at all under U.S. U.C.C. section 3-415. See generally, ELLINGER, supra note 2, § 443. Under<br />

LC law, when the beneficiary draws a draft, it incurs liability as the drawer in the event that it is<br />

dishonored. When the payee (sometimes also the beneficiary) indorses the draft in blank or to the<br />

negotiating bank or its order, it also incurs liability as an indorser. In the event of dishonor, the person<br />

entitled to enforce the draft has recourse on the instrument against prior indorsers and the drawer unless<br />

that liability has been disclaimed, waived, or discharged. Failure to give timely notice of dishonor of an<br />

instrument to an indorser who is not the principal obligor can result in discharge of the indorser's liability.<br />

See U.C.C. § 3-415(c). Since the indorser is typically in a zero-sum position, having paid and received<br />

funds for the instrument as it is received and subsequently transferred, the requirement of timely notice is<br />

proper so that it can move promptly to protect its position. Where there is a subsequent acceptance, under<br />

some local laws the liability of a prior indorser is discharged. See U.C.C. § 3-415(d).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 577 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

confirming banks has been stated in the various versions of the UCP, there is no<br />

right of recourse even were the UCP not to so state. 6 Having undertaken to honor,<br />

these banks are obligated on the credit, and payment by them is final in favor of the<br />

beneficiary. 47 The notion is therefore linked to finality. The issuer or confirmer<br />

bears the risk of paying against discrepant documents or obtaining reimbursement.<br />

Should the issuer or confirmer have made an erroneous or unlucky credit decision or<br />

have erred as to whether or not the documents are discrepant, it may not seek<br />

recourse against the beneficiary after it has negotiated. 8<br />

Were a draft indorsed without disclaiming recourse on the draft, the issue arises<br />

as to whether there is recourse under negotiable instruments law. Where recourse<br />

can be disclaimed other than on the face of negotiable instrument, the terms of the<br />

UCP could suffice as a disclaimer as to the issuer or confirmer who undertakes to<br />

negotiate. 9 Where they cannot be, there is a conflict between the two regimes. In<br />

such a situation, negotiable instrument law should be displaced by the law of letters<br />

of credit 5 °<br />

A different result obtains where a bank other than the confirmer is nominated<br />

to negotiate under the letter of credit. The UCP does not address this situation. It is<br />

thought that the general rule of negotiable instruments-that there is recourse unless<br />

it is disclaimed-applies in such a situation, although its contours are debated."<br />

There is considerable debate over the scope of recourse, particularly whether or not<br />

46. Recourse was not mentioned in UCP82 (1933). It first appeared in UCP151 Article 5 (1951),<br />

which provided that "[i]n case of credits available by negotiation of drafts, the confirmation implies only<br />

the undertaking of the confirming Bank to negotiate drafts without recourse to drawer." UCP290 Article 3<br />

(1974) recognized that the issuer did not negotiate with recourse, and this approach continued until<br />

UCP600, which drops reference to negotiation by the issuer and seeks to forbid drafts drawn on the<br />

applicant-impotently, since the terms of the credit can vary the rules. UCP600 Article 8 (a)(ii)<br />

(Confirming Bank Undertaking) continues to recognize that a confirmer negotiates without recourse.<br />

Even without these references, payment under a letter of credit by a bank obligated as an issuer or<br />

confirmer is final. This principle will be relevant with respect to drafts drawn on the applicant, or a third<br />

person, under UCP600, which does not contain such a provision.<br />

47. An exception to this principle is letter of credit fraud on the part of the beneficiary. But the value<br />

of a right against the fraudster beneficiary is questionable.<br />

48. It is necessary, however, to distinguish between recourse against the beneficiary on the LC<br />

payment and any other rights that the applicant may have against the beneficiary that may be assigned to<br />

the bank or to which the bank may be subrogated. See Revised U.C.C. § 5-117 (revised 1995) (Subrogation<br />

of Issuer, Applicant, and Nominated Person) (offering a complete statement of subrogation). These rights<br />

depend on whether the beneficiary has breached its contract with the applicant and do not relate to the<br />

letter of credit or the documentary character of the presentation.<br />

49. See ELLINGER, supra note 2, § 373 n.817 (citing cases for the proposition that recourse may be<br />

disclaimed in a collateral document or even verbally). The omission from UCP600 of any reference to<br />

negotiation by an issuer and, correspondingly, negotiation without recourse, could be problematic where a<br />

UCP600 credit provided for a draft drawn on the applicant. The correct rule, however, is that negotiation<br />

under such a credit by the issuer is without recourse.<br />

50. See, e.g., Revised U.C.C. § 5-116(d) (showing a preference for the law of letters of credit by stating<br />

that "[i]f there is a conflict between this article and Article 3, 4, 4A, or 9, this article governs"). The two<br />

systems could be reconciled by reference to the UCP non-recourse provision. It could be concluded that<br />

this provision constitutes a disclaimer of the right to recourse. That theory, however, would not work with<br />

respect to negotiation by an issuer under UCP600. The failure of UCP600 to address negotiation by an<br />

issuer of a draft drawn on the applicant or another person gives rise to the question of whether the<br />

principle of finality will be applied without an express reference in the UCP. While it should be, a prudent<br />

beneficiary will require that the credit so state or draw and endorse the draft without recourse.<br />

51. A negotiating bank does not rely solely on reimbursement from the issuer or confirmer. In the<br />

event that the issuer and confirmer are insolvent and prevented by the laws of their countries from<br />

effecting reimbursement, it can have recourse against the beneficiary. U.C.C. § 5-110 (2006).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 578 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

it extends to errors regarding discrepancies on the part of the negotiating bank (or at<br />

least those discrepancies that could have been cured). 2 While practices differ, and<br />

banks are free to disclaim or waive their right to recourse, the concept itself admits<br />

of no such distinction. In effect, some banks distinguish themselves in their market,<br />

or are pressured by others in their market, by voluntarily assuming the risk of bank<br />

error with respect to missed discrepancies. Other risks include issuing bank risk,<br />

country risk, currency risk, and risk of beneficiary fraud. Unless expressly<br />

disclaimed, it is generally thought that these risks rest with the beneficiary instead of<br />

the negotiating bank.<br />

F<br />

Protection of Banks That Negotiate in the Event of LC Fraud<br />

One of the critical tests of the workability of any aspect of commercial law is<br />

the manner in which it addresses issues of fraud and balances the relative rights of<br />

various parties and broader commercial interests in the integrity of the institution it<br />

governs.<br />

It is with respect to fraud that negotiable instruments are most commonly<br />

distinguished from traditional contracts 3 The entity to whom a negotiable<br />

instrument is negotiated qualifies for greater rights that may have been possessed by<br />

the transferor. This abstraction of the rights inherent in the paper from the<br />

transaction that gave rise to it is the hallmark of the doctrine of negotiability.<br />

Letters of credit take this abstraction to a higher level.<br />

Generally speaking, under the common law of negotiable instruments, there is<br />

an entire apparatus of substantive and procedural law designed to support the notion<br />

of negotiability. On negotiation, a presumption can be said to arise that a person to<br />

whom a draft has been negotiated, or one who claims under that person, is entitled<br />

to recover on the instrument unless the person obligated on the instrument is able to<br />

prove a defense. The defense may be any defense that sounds in contract or<br />

recoupment. Once a defense is proven, the holder who has acted with good faith is<br />

entitled to a protected status either in its own right or in that of a person under<br />

whom it claims. Even if it is so entitled, there are certain defenses deemed so basic<br />

that this protection fails as to them. 4<br />

The law of fraud with respect to letters of credit is a relatively recent creation,<br />

dating its origins by most accounts to the 1941 decision of the New York Supreme<br />

Court (a trial court of general jurisdiction) in Sztejn v. J. Henry Shroeder Banking<br />

Corp. 55<br />

52. What the fees paid by beneficiaries for negotiation cover, if not examination for discrepancies, is a<br />

persuasive question.<br />

53. A stimulating revisionist study suggests that the doctrine of negotiability emerged from the<br />

common law system itself in response to economic requirements of the late 18th century, challenging the<br />

notion that it was an assimilation of the law merchant. JAMES S. ROGERS, THE EARLY HISTORY OF THE<br />

LAW OF BILLS AND NOTES (1995). Whatever the historical antecedents, there is no doubt that by the end<br />

of the nineteenth century, negotiable instruments were distinct from the traditional doctrine of assignment<br />

under contract law by which the assignee took subject to defenses against the assignor.<br />

54. See generally ELLINGER, supra note 2, § 417.<br />

55. 31 N.Y.S.2d 631, 634 (N.Y.Sup.Ct., 1941)<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 579 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

When bankers hear of a bank being embroiled in a dispute between an<br />

applicant and a beneficiary, they sometimes express the wistful opinion that the<br />

letter of credit should operate without regard to fraud. Upon being pressed,<br />

however, they generally do not mean that it should be fraud-proof. With the<br />

possible exception of the U.K., 6 courts have generally grasped this point for the very<br />

good reason that an instrument that can be used with impunity by fraudsters loses its<br />

credibility as readily as one whose liquidity can be frozen based on any dispute over<br />

the transaction that gave rise to it. The challenge is to find a balance that favors the<br />

integrity of the letter of credit while providing a remedy for the rare case where<br />

letter of credit fraud is sufficiently demonstrated and the merits of judicial<br />

intervention are apparent. 57<br />

There are several dimensions to LC fraud that involve negotiation by issuers,<br />

confirmers, and negotiating banks under letter of credit practice and law that<br />

externally resemble the law of negotiable instruments, but that manifest significant<br />

differences. While the courts that have decided cases on this topic commonly recite<br />

or draw on principles of negotiable instruments law, it is not entirely clear that they<br />

appreciate the differences.<br />

1. The Presumption of Entitlement<br />

Under negotiable instruments law, it is the holder or a person claiming under it<br />

who is entitled to a presumption of entitlement (that they are entitled to exercise<br />

rights free of the transferor and recover), which narrowly circumscribes the defenses<br />

that can be asserted. On the other hand, where there is no transfer by negotiation,<br />

any defense between the drawer and the person to whom the draft is issued (usually<br />

the payee) can be asserted.<br />

Under letter of credit law, it is the beneficiary (in a situation roughly<br />

comparable to the payee) who is effectively so entitled and, unlike a negotiable<br />

instrument, even where there is no negotiation, the defenses that are able to be<br />

asserted against the beneficiary are severely circumscribed and effectively limited.<br />

The protected person in LC law and practice is immune to even these defenses, and<br />

thus, the scope of the doctrine of negotiability under a letter of credit is much<br />

broader than is the case with a negotiable instrument.<br />

Under letter of credit practice and law, the applicant bears the risk of disputes<br />

regarding the performance of the underlying transactions that gave rise to the letter<br />

of credit. In effect, the letter of credit represents an allocation of the risk of who<br />

holds funds pending the resolution of these disputes. In the ordinary case under a<br />

letter of credit, the beneficiary is entitled to hold the funds until things can be sorted<br />

56. While the English courts recite the proposition that injunctive relief is available in the event of<br />

letter of credit fraud, there is no case in which it has been awarded. Indeed, the approach of the English<br />

courts to letter of credit fraud has with few exceptions been an exercise in distorting letter of credit<br />

practice. See, e.g., Banco Santander S.A. v. Bayfern Ltd. & Ors., [1999] 2 All E.R. (Comm.) (Q.B.) 18,<br />

affd Banco Santander SA v. Banque Paribas, [2000] 1 All E.R. (Comm.) (C.A.) 776. The definitive study<br />

of English LC fraud law has yet to be written. What exists is either written by apologists or by treatise<br />

writers whose mission is to explain within the context of the system rather than to analyze in a critical<br />

mode.<br />

57. See generally GAO XIANG, THE FRAUD RULE ON THE LAW OF LETrERS OF CREDIT: A<br />

COMPARATIVE STUDY (2002) (examining the problems surrounding letter of credit fraud).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 580 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

out." Although payment to the beneficiary is final with respect to the letter of credit<br />

obligation, the obligation that gave rise to it remains and may be a basis for recovery<br />

by the applicant to the credit or any assignee of its rights in a post-payment action<br />

against the beneficiary on the underlying transaction. The abstract status of the<br />

beneficiary, therefore, can be understood as temporary or interim. That of the LC<br />

issuer or nominated bank is permanent. The rule protects these banks, as it should,<br />

if the system is to have currency, since where these banks, as intermediaries, have in<br />

good faith paid funds to the fraudster pursuant to their undertaking or nomination,<br />

they ought to be able to obtain reimbursement. Assuming that lending or credit<br />

decisions were sound, the loss will be thrown onto the applicant who either elected<br />

to deal with the beneficiary or used its credit to obtain the LC for the person who did<br />

SO.<br />

2. What Defense Is Good Against a Beneficiary? The LC Fraud Exception<br />

to the Independence Principle<br />

Under negotiable instruments law, the proof of a defense brings into question<br />

entitlement under a protected status. 59 Only if this status is present will the holder of<br />

the instrument recover, and then only with respect to certain defenses. Defenses are<br />

cut off by a protected holder. However, depending on the system, there are certain<br />

58. So potent is the abstract status afforded the beneficiary that the transferee beneficiary is immune<br />

from defenses, including LC fraud, that could be asserted against the original beneficiary. See Banca del<br />

Sempione v. Provident Bank of Maryland, 160 F.3d 992, 995-96 (4th Cir. 1998). The abstract explanation<br />

of LC transfers which differs considerably from assignment of a contract, see, e.g., ISP98, supra note 10, R.<br />

6.01-6.05, is beyond the scope of this paper. The letter of credit makes this allocation possible by providing<br />

that the beneficiary is entitled to honor provided that the documents comply on their face with the terms<br />

and conditions of the letter of credit and without regard to disputes about the underlying transaction. This<br />

principle is the independence doctrine, which captures the documentary and abstract character of the letter<br />

of credit. The principle is best formulated in ISP98 Rule 1.06(c) (Nature of Standbys), which provides:<br />

Because a standby is independent, the enforceability of an issuer's obligations under a standby<br />

does not depend on: i. the issuer's right or ability to obtain reimbursement from the applicant;<br />

ii. the beneficiary's right to obtain payment from the applicant; iii. a reference in the standby to<br />

any reimbursement agreement or underlying transaction; or iv. the issuer's knowledge of<br />

performance or breach of any reimbursement agreement or underlying transaction.<br />

It is also scattered throughout the UCP. See, e.g., UCP600 arts. 4 (Credits v. Contracts), 5 (Documents v.<br />

Goods, Services or Performance) (2007); see also U.S. Revised U.C.C. § 5-103(d) (revised 1995); United<br />

Nations Convention on Independent Guarantees and Stand-by Letters of Credit, G.A. Res. 50/48, art. 3,<br />

U.N. Doc. A/RES/50/48 (Jan. 26, 1996) [hereinafter U.N. LC Convention].<br />

59. One of the chief differences between the common law and the civil law systems relates to the<br />

consequence of the proof of a defense. Under the Bills of Exchange Act, a holder in due course is<br />

distinguished from a holder for value or a mere holder. 1882, 45 & 46 Vict. c. 61, § 29. Under section 30(2)<br />

of the Act, every holder is presumed to be a holder unless the defense is fraud, illegality, or duress, in<br />

which case the holder must prove its entitled status. Under U.C.C. section 3-308 (2006), a holder is entitled<br />

to recover unless the person obligated on the instrument proves any defense good in contract, in which<br />

case the holder or person claiming under its rights must prove in all respects that it is a holder in due<br />

course. Under Article 16 of the Geneva Convention, supra note 2, the focus is on the regular acquisition of<br />

the instrument through a series of facially proper indorsements without regard to their authenticity. Only<br />

if it has acquired the bill in bad faith does the holder not acquire good title to the instrument. See generally<br />

ELLINGER. supra note 2, §§ 404-27. The differences between these presumptions and the relative burdens<br />

attendant on them sheds some light on the absence of uniformity with respect to the presumptions to be<br />

accorded to a nominated bank or an issuer, where the issuer arises under letter of credit law and practice.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 581 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

defenses based in public policy, such as incapacity, that can be asserted even against<br />

a protected holder. 6° Under the civil law, a person obligated on a bill "cannot set up<br />

against the holder defenses founded on their personal relations with the drawer or<br />

with previous holders, unless the holder, in acquiring the bill, has knowingly acted to<br />

the detriment of the holder." 1 In effect, defenses that are "personal defenses related<br />

to the bill and the underlying transaction" are excluded. 62 However, certain defenses<br />

are good even against a good faith holder. Ellinger lists them as incapacity, forgery<br />

of the drawer's signature, and duress. Under the American system, once a defense<br />

in contract or recoupment is proven, the burden of proof shifts to the holder to the<br />

prove holder in due course status. Even if proven, a holder in due course takes the<br />

instrument subject to "real" defenses (in rem) of infancy, duress, lack of capacity,<br />

illegality (which nullifies the undertaking under local law), and fraud resulting under<br />

excusable ignorance. 63 The English system differs in this respect. A holder's rights<br />

"are easily assailable."" A holder in due course takes the instrument free of title<br />

defects and fraud relating to the underlying transaction. 6 Ellinger characterizes the<br />

position as "iron-clad," subject only to defenses of capacity or consent, such as a plea<br />

of non est factum when a party is tricked into signing a bill, which closely resembles<br />

the defense of fraud due to excusable ignorance under U.S. law.'<br />

In an LC scenario, the beneficiary takes free of defenses that could be asserted<br />

under negotiable instruments law against a holder who had not proven its protected<br />

status. In effect, the level of abstraction for negotiable instruments is ratcheted up a<br />

notch and narrowed compared to the law of negotiable instruments.<br />

Under letter of credit law, it is the equivalent of one of these "real" defenses (as<br />

opposed to "personal" defenses) of negotiable instruments law 67 that gives rise to an<br />

excuse to the letter of credit obligation in the face a demand by the beneficiary. A<br />

defense that is "personal" to the applicant and beneficiary is not a defense to an LC<br />

unless it is LC fraud. The other "real" defenses to negotiable instruments are not, as<br />

a practical matter, likely to arise in the case of letters of credit.' As a result,<br />

defenses that can be asserted under letter of credit practice are limited to fraud on<br />

the part of the beneficiary that is so serious as to render the pretense of operating on<br />

the basis of documentary representations meaningless. There are a variety of names<br />

for this fraud, and even more descriptions of it. 69 For purposes of convenience, and<br />

60. See U.C.C. § 3-305(a)(1) (2006); U.N. Bills of Exchange Convention, supra note 2, art. 30(1)(c).<br />

See generally ELLINGER, supra note 2, §§ 417-27.<br />

61. Geneva Convention on Bills of Exchange, supra note 2. art. 17.<br />

62. ELLINGER, supra note 2, § 425.<br />

63. U.C.C. §§ 3-305(a), 3-308 (2006).<br />

64. ELLINGER, supra note 2, § 417.<br />

65. Id.; Bills of Exchange Act, 1882, 45 & 46 Vict. c. 61, § 38(2).<br />

66. ELLINGER, supra note 2, § 418 n.903; U.N. Bills of Exchange Convention, supra note 2, art.<br />

30(1)(b).<br />

67. Real defenses are those that can be asserted even against a holder in due course. They include<br />

infancy, duress, lack of legal capacity, illegality that nullifies the transaction, essential fraud resulting from<br />

excusable ignorance, and discharge in insolvency. See, e.g., U.C.C. § 3-305(a)(1) (2006).<br />

68. Since letters of credit are not consumer devices, only the defense of fraud could be asserted by a<br />

bank issuing a letter of credit. Illegality is not a defense under letter of credit law or practice. If a bank has<br />

issued a letter of credit, it must live with the consequences, which may include regulatory or criminal<br />

sanctions, but its error should not excuse its obligation to a beneficiary. Illegal conduct by the beneficiary<br />

is a matter of local statutory or regulatory law. The definitive study of illegality with respect to LCs<br />

remains to be written.<br />

69. There is no definitive study of LC fraud. A valuable beginning has been essayed in XIANG GAO,<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 582 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

to distinguish it from other types of fraud-including fraud in the inducement<br />

(procurement), securities fraud, and misrepresentation-this type of fraud is called<br />

"letter of credit fraud" (or "LC fraud") in this article.<br />

The word "fraud" is unfortunate. In the civil law system, the name "fraud"<br />

suggests criminal complicity, and what is meant by LC fraud perhaps is better<br />

captured by the notion of abusive drawing (abus de droit). In the common law<br />

system, it connotes scienter or intent on the part of the fraudster. It is this<br />

unfortunate connection that has led to a series of decisions by various courts to the<br />

effect that a beneficiary is entitled to recover from a bank where a required<br />

document that it presents is fraudulent (forged or otherwise fraudulent), but where<br />

the beneficiary is innocent of the fraud. 7 " This result reflects a misunderstanding of<br />

the undertaking inherent in a letter of credit. A letter of credit bank undertakes to<br />

honor a document that represents the underlying transaction. It does not undertake<br />

to honor a document that is fraudulent regardless of the innocence of the person<br />

presenting it. Where there is no question of reimbursement of a protected bank that<br />

has honored or negotiated against documents that on their face comply with the<br />

terms and conditions of the credit, the risk of documentary fraud is on the innocent<br />

beneficiary who dealt with the fraudulent document where the issuer or confirmer is<br />

able to prove its fraudulent character and resists payment on that basis. As to the<br />

issuer, confirmer, or other nominated bank, the beneficiary's obligation is to present<br />

a genuine document. The ability of the issuer or confirmer to refuse payment to a<br />

beneficiary or a collecting bank on the basis of letter of credit fraud should not be<br />

confused with its right to recover reimbursement, notwithstanding that fraud where<br />

it honors in good faith.<br />

supra note 58. Revised U.C.C. section 5-109(a) (Fraud and Forgery) (revised 1995) provides that LC fraud<br />

arises:<br />

[i]f a presentation is made that appears on its face strictly to comply with the terms and<br />

conditions of the letter of credit, but a required document is forged or materially fraudulent, or<br />

honor of the presentation would facilitate a material fraud by the beneficiary on the issuer or<br />

applicant ....<br />

U.N. LC Convention, supra note 58, article 19 states that it is present:<br />

[i]f it is manifest and clear that: (a) Any document is not genuine or has been falsified; (b) No<br />

payment is due on the basis asserted in the demand and the supporting documents; or (c)<br />

Judging by the type and purpose of the undertaking, the demand has no conceivable basis ....<br />

The Interpretation of the Sup. People's Ct. (PRC) [2005] No. 13 Article 8 states:<br />

The letter of credit fraud shall be determined as constituted under any of the following<br />

circumstances: (1)The beneficiary forges documents or provides documents containing<br />

fraudulent information; (2) The beneficiary maliciously refuses to deliver goods or delivers<br />

goods of no value: (3) The beneficiary provides false documents by colluding with the applicant<br />

or a third party and there isn't any true basic transaction: or (4) Other circumstances under<br />

which letter of credit fraud is conducted.<br />

70. See Credit Industriel et Commercial v. China Merchants Bank, (2002) 1 All E.R. (Comm.) (Q.B.)<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 583 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

3. The LC Exception to the Fraud Defense: Protected Persons<br />

As indicated, the effect of protected holder status under negotiable instruments<br />

law entitles its occupant to recover notwithstanding certain defenses. Once a real<br />

defense such as fraud resulting from trickery is proven, a protected holder is subject<br />

to it under negotiable instruments law.<br />

Even where it is proven that there is Letter of Credit Fraud, recovery under an<br />

LC is not prevented for protected parties to the letter of credit transaction who are<br />

able to claim reimbursement notwithstanding beneficiary letter of credit fraud.<br />

There is no equivalent in negotiable instruments law, under which the protected<br />

parties only are protected against personal defenses, but not against real ones. The<br />

LC protection is, so to speak, supercharged.<br />

The protected status of banks under letter of credit practice must be pieced<br />

together from rules of practice and their implications. Bankers are rarely interested<br />

in formulating rules addressing pathological problems. 7 ' The foundation of this<br />

supercharged protected status, however, can be seen in UCP600 Article 34<br />

(Disclaimer on Effectiveness of Documents). It disclaims all liability and<br />

responsibility of banks for the "genuineness, falsification ... of any document(s), or<br />

for the general or particular conditions stipulated in a document or superimposed<br />

thereon; nor does it assume any liability or responsibility for the ... existence of the<br />

goods, services or other performance represented by any document, or for the good<br />

faith or acts or omissions, . . . performance ... of ... any other person." 72 The new<br />

provisions in UCP600 Articles 7(c) (Issuing Bank Obligation), 8(c) (Confirming<br />

Bank Obligation), and 12(b) (Nomination) also address the issue of the right to<br />

reimbursement in the event of LC fraud. In the absence of a statute, these<br />

provisions provide a useful framework for the fraud exception, but in the absence of<br />

a systematic treatment of LC fraud, it is doubtful that courts will be able to build a<br />

comprehensive jurisprudence, particularly where they have gotten off to a false start.<br />

While rules of practice cannot themselves create exceptions to the legal effect<br />

to be given to fraudulent or abusive drawings, they can allocate the risk of such<br />

actions, and modern commercial law typically gives effect to such an allocation if it is<br />

commercially reasonable. 73 Under standard international letter of credit practice,<br />

where an issuer or nominated bank acting pursuant to its nomination honors, the risk<br />

of fraud or forgery is allocated to the applicant.<br />

71. ISP98 Rule 1.05(c) (Exclusion of Matters Related to Due Issuance and Fraudulent or Abusive<br />

Drawing) defers to applicable law. But see The Official Commentary, supra note 10, Rule 1.05, cmt. 5(c),<br />

20-21 (delineating the exceptions that are implicit in LC practice).<br />

72. The first version of this article was UCP82 (1933) Article 11, followed by UCPI51 (1951) Article<br />

11, which was identical. The rule was rephrased and expanded slightly in UCP222 (1962) Article 9.<br />

UCP290 (1974) Article 9 and UCP400 (1983) Article 17 were identical to UCP222 Article 9. UCP500<br />

(1993) Article 15 again slightly rephrased and expanded the rule.<br />

73. See ISP98, supra note 10, R. 1.05(c) (Exclusion of Matters Related to Due Issuance and<br />

Fraudulent or Abusive Drawing) (stating that "[tihese Rules do not define or otherwise provide for: a.<br />

power or authority to issue a standby; b. formal requirements for execution of a standby (e.g. a signed<br />

writing); or c. defenses to honour based on fraud, abuse, or similar matters. These matters are left to<br />

applicable law"). Despite this provision, however, it is noted that "[w]hile ISP98 provides no systematic<br />

rule with respect to fraud or abuse, it does contain rules based on principles which would provide<br />

important guidance in determining whether and what remedy might be appropriate in the event of fraud."<br />

The Official Commentary, supra note 10, at 20-21.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 584 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

4. Nomination<br />

Under the law of negotiable instruments, any person to whom an instrument<br />

has been transferred by negotiation is eligible for protected status provided that they<br />

behave with the requisite good faith, give value, and act without notice of a defense<br />

or that the instrument is overdue.<br />

The availability of this protected status under LCs does not, in the first instance,<br />

turn on the relative culpability or innocence of the person or entity involved. As<br />

discussed above, a protected status is only available to those who have issued the LC<br />

or been nominated to act under the letter of credit. 7 " Thus, where the LC involves an<br />

undertaking to negotiate drafts by the issuer, confirmer, or a negotiating bank,<br />

protected status extends only to the nominated bank or the issuer. A bank that acts<br />

without nomination (a collecting bank) takes subject to any defense that can be<br />

asserted against the beneficiary.<br />

While the test of the bank's good faith and the burden of proving it are<br />

procedural matters under local law, whether a bank is nominated to negotiate will be<br />

apparent from the face of the credit or amendments. 75<br />

If an issuer or nominated bank acts pursuant to its nomination, the risk of the<br />

consequences of LC fraud of any other person is allocated to the applicant. The<br />

nominated bank is entitled to be reimbursed for any payment made pursuant to any<br />

obligation occurred provided that the nominated bank has not itself been a party to<br />

the fraud, abuse, or forgery.<br />

If the issuer, confirmer, or negotiating bank duly negotiates, it is entitled to<br />

protected status notwithstanding LC fraud. But what constitutes due negotiation<br />

differs between banks that are irrevocably obligated on the letter of credit and those<br />

that are not-that is, between issuing and confirming banks on the one hand and<br />

negotiating banks on the other hand.<br />

74. The entitlement of a transferee of a letter of credit to protection from the LC fraud of the<br />

beneficiary is a topic that is beyond the scope of this paper. It arises from what is, in effect, a separate or<br />

new LC and not from the process of negotiation of the documents under the original LC. As will be<br />

apparent, the transfer of a letter of credit differs greatly from the transfer of a chose in action under<br />

general commercial law.<br />

75. The question becomes somewhat more complex where the nominated bank is a negotiating bank.<br />

In such a situation, letter of credit law often becomes entangled with the law of negotiable instruments, and<br />

it is common for the courts to look to the procedures, allocations of burdens of proof, and presumptions<br />

related to the doctrine of holder in due course. While this doctrine is related, the presumptions<br />

surrounding acceptance financing are more useful than those of negotiable instruments law. That body of<br />

law reflects a situation where there is an established market and practice of trade finance through the sale<br />

and purchase of abstracted rights, and it has been less susceptible to concerns of issuers of commercial<br />

paper who are also consumers and invoke consumer protection doctrines to limit the effect of negotiability.<br />

It should be sufficient to establish a prima facie entitlement to recover if a negotiating bank provides a<br />

sworn statement of the facts surrounding its negotiation.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 585 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

a. Protected Status Where There Is Negotiation by the Issuing or<br />

Confirming Bank<br />

As indicated, under negotiable instrument law, a protected person is entitled to<br />

limited protection. Under all systems, even a protected person is vulnerable to<br />

certain defenses founded in trickery regarding the instrument or fraud in the factum.<br />

Under letter of credit practice and law, an issuing bank and a confirming bank,<br />

having undertaken to honor, are entitled to the enhanced protected status available<br />

under letter of credit practice and law, which enables them to be reimbursed<br />

regardless of the nature of the defense against the beneficiary where they have acted<br />

in good faith, that is, without actual knowledge of the fraud and for value. 76<br />

Where the issuer or confirmer have given their irrevocable promise, there is no<br />

question of value. The need to have given value can be said to be met by having<br />

made an irrevocable promise or to be irrelevant where there is such a promise." In<br />

either event, value is not an issue.<br />

Notice of default or that the undertaking is overdue, issues under the law of<br />

negotiable instruments, are inapt as letter of credit categories. If the default relates<br />

to the underlying transaction, the issuer or confirmer can ignore it unless they have<br />

actual indisputable knowledge of the default and are aware that the default is so<br />

serious that it disentitles the beneficiary to any conceivable right to draw. There is<br />

no notion of a LC being "overdue" applicable to letters of credit. If the credit has<br />

expired-that is, ceased to be available for a presentation-the obligation of an<br />

issuer or confirmer is discharged, and if a deadline has passed," 6 the documents do<br />

not comply, and the bank is not entitled to be reimbursed unless waived by the issuer<br />

or applicant respectively.<br />

As to notice of fraud, the right to reimbursement of an issuer or confirmer who<br />

has made an irrevocable undertaking to honor is not affected by notice of fraud<br />

provided that they act in good faith. 7 9 For this purpose, the notion of "good faith" is<br />

76. The risks of fraud, abuse, or false or forged documents are not assumed by any bank, including an<br />

issuer or confirmer. This protected status is implicit in the concept of negotiation under standard<br />

international letter of credit practice. See UCP500 (1994) art. 15; ISP98 art. 8.01(b).<br />

77. See U.C.C. § 3-303(a)(4) & (5) (2006) (stating that "[a]n instrument is issued or transferred for<br />

value if: ... (4) the instrument is issued or transferred in exchange for a negotiable instrument; or (5) the<br />

instrument is issued or transferred in exchange for the incurring of an irrevocable obligation to a third<br />

party by the person taking the instrument").<br />

78. Letters of credit often contain various deadlines such as a period of time after the issuance of the<br />

transport document within which documents must be presented-the default rule is twenty-one days under<br />

UCP600 Article 14(c) (Standard for Examination of Documents)-and a deadline by which the transport<br />

document must be issued.<br />

79. U.C.C. Revised section 5-109(a) (revised 1995) provides:<br />

If a presentation is made that appears on its face strictly to comply with the terms and<br />

conditions of the letter of credit, but a required document is forged or materially fraudulent, or<br />

honor of the presentation would facilitate a material fraud by the beneficiary on the issuer or<br />

applicant: (1) the issuer shall honor the presentation, if honor is demanded by (i) a nominated<br />

person who has given value in good faith and without notice of forgery or material fraud, (ii) a<br />

confirmer who has honored its confirmation in good faith, (iii) a holder in due course of a draft<br />

drawn under the letter of credit which was taken after acceptance by the issuer or nominated<br />

person, or (iv) an assignee of the issuer's or nominated person's deferred obligation that was<br />

taken for value and without notice of forgery or material fraud after the obligation was<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 586 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

limited severely. Under negotiable instruments law, the focus of the inquiry of<br />

whether one has acted in good faith is on the time when the purchase takes place.<br />

Under a letter of credit, an issuer or confirmer are already obligated, and their only<br />

focus is on the documents and not the underlying transaction. Their "good faith"<br />

relates only to what actual knowledge they have about the documents. They are<br />

under no duty to investigate allegations or suspicions. A bank acts in good faith<br />

unless it has actual and incontrovertible knowledge of letter of credit fraud,<br />

Therefore, the mere allegation of fraud by the applicant will not impede recovery by<br />

the issuer or confirmer. 8 '<br />

This rule exists to protect the letter of credit system. If the mere allegation of<br />

fraud were sufficient to inhibit a letter of credit promise to pay, it would be of little<br />

more value than a simple contract. Banks do not and should not have the power to<br />

make a binding determination of the validity of claims of letter of credit fraud, and<br />

cannot compel the submission of evidence. Therefore, they should not be placed in<br />

the position of an investigator. The starkness of this result for the applicant is<br />

ameliorated by the ability of the applicant to seek extraordinary judicial relief in the<br />

form of a special court order attaching or freezing the presentation, payment, or<br />

proceeds.'<br />

incurred by the issuer or nominated person; and (2) the issuer, acting in good faith, may honor<br />

or dishonor the presentation in any other case.<br />

U.N. LC Convention, supra note 58, Article 19 provides:<br />

(1) If it is manifest and clear that: (a) Any document is not genuine or has been falsified; (b) No<br />

payment is due on the basis asserted in the demand and the supporting documents or (c)<br />

Judging by the type and purpose of the undertaking, the demand has no conceivable basis, the<br />

guarantor/issuer, acting in good faith, has a right, as against the beneficiary, to withhold<br />

payment.<br />

The Interpretation of the Supreme People's Court (PRC) [2005] No. 13 Article 10 provides:<br />

A people's court shall make a ruling to suspend the payment or a judgement to permanently<br />

stop the payment under a Credit when fraud is established, unless one of the following has<br />

happened: (i) The nominated person or the person authorised by the issuing bank has paid in<br />

good faith in accordance with the instructions of the issuing bank; (ii) The issuing bank or its<br />

nominated or authorized person has accepted the bills of exchange under the Credit in good<br />

faith; (iii) The confirming bank has paid in good faith; or (iv) The negotiating bank has<br />

negotiated in good faith.<br />

80. It has been properly suggested that such a situation would only arise when the documents are<br />

marked "fraudulent." Short of that, it is difficult to imagine a situation where actual knowledge of fraud<br />

could be visited on the issuer or confirmer, unless it or its employees have colluded in the fraud.<br />

81. The issuer or confirmer, however, may at its option refuse payment based on LC fraud. Should<br />

they do so, usually when the applicant has undertaken to indemnify them and hold them harmless from any<br />

losses or expenses, they are required to prove that there has been LC fraud. This action is discretionary<br />

except in the rare situation where the bank is certain of the existence of fraud. In most situations, the bank<br />

will not elect to expose itself-or its reputation-to the risk of having to prove fraud in relationship to a<br />

transaction in which it is not involved.<br />

82. U.C.C. § 5-109(b) (2006) provides:<br />

If an applicant claims that a required document is forged or materially fraudulent or that honor<br />

of the presentation would facilitate a material fraud by the beneficiary on the issuer or<br />

applicant, a court of competent jurisdiction may temporarily or permanently enjoin the issuer<br />

from honoring a presentation or grant similar relief against the issuer or other persons ....<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 587 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

b. Protected Status Where There Is Negotiation by a Negotiating Bank<br />

A bank that is nominated to negotiate without adding its confirmation is a<br />

negotiating bank and, should it elect to negotiate and duly do so, is entitled to<br />

reimbursement by the issuer or confirmer." As to negotiation by a nominated<br />

negotiating bank other than the confirmer, a different regime exists, and it is<br />

necessary to revisit the elements of protected status.<br />

5. Value<br />

In the law of negotiable instruments, there is some confusion as to the<br />

relationship between value and negotiation. The absence of an exchange may in the<br />

common law systems constitute a defense to the enforceability of the instrument, but<br />

should be unrelated to the question of whether or not it has been negotiated. Only<br />

in the U.S. system, however, is this distinction made. There, value is a question that<br />

arises in regard to whether the person to whom the instrument has been negotiated<br />

is entitled to a protected status. What constitutes value is a matter of some interest<br />

in comparing the U.K. and U.S. system.<br />

U.S. negotiable instruments law distinguishes between "consideration" and<br />

"value," concluding that an executory promise is good consideration, but not "value"<br />

The U.N. Bills of Exchange Convention, supra note 2, Article 20 provides:<br />

(1) Where, on an application by the principal/applicant or the instructing party, it is shown that<br />

there is a high probability that, with regard to a demand made, or expected to be made, by the<br />

beneficiary, one of the circumstances referred to in subparagraphs (a), (b) and (c) of paragraph<br />

(1) of article 19 [Exception to Payment Obligation] is present, the court, on the basis of<br />

immediately available strong evidence, may: (a) Issue a provisional order to the effect that the<br />

beneficiary does not receive payment, including an order that the guarantor/issuer hold the<br />

amount of the undertaking, or (b) Issue a provisional order to the effect that the proceeds of<br />

the undertaking paid to the beneficiary are blocked, taking into account whether in the absence<br />

of such an order the principal/applicant would be likely to suffer serious harm.<br />

See Chinese LC Rules, supra note 79, art. 10; see also U.N. Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong><br />

[UNCITRAL], Working Group on International Contract Practices, Independent Guarantees and Stand-by<br />

Letters of Credit: Discussion of Further Issues of a Uniform <strong>Law</strong>: Fraud and Other Objections to Payment,<br />

Injunctions and Other Court Measures: note by the Secretariat, paras. 90-114, U.N. Doc.<br />

A/CN.9/WG.II/WP.70 (Apr. 5, 1991).<br />

83. No distinction is made here between a bank that is specially nominated to negotiate and a freely<br />

negotiable credit since both operate identically with respect to negotiation. A freely negotiable credit<br />

permits negotiation without designating a specific bank, so that any bank may negotiate. As with<br />

negotiation, there is no required or typical manner of indicating that the credit is freely negotiable. Free<br />

negotiation may be indicated by a recital that the issuer undertakes to honor presentations by any bank or<br />

by stating that the credit is freely negotiable, by checking a box on a form, or by so stating in SWIFT Field<br />

41a (Available With... By... ). A variation on free negotiation is a credit that is freely negotiable within<br />

a stated geographical area (e.g., "negotiable by any bank in Singapore"). Under a freely negotiable credit,<br />

any bank is a nominated person under the credit, except that it may not effect a transfer of drawing rights<br />

unless it is specifically nominated as a transferring bank. There are operational risks associated with free<br />

negotiation regarding control of the documents and presentation in that the issuer and applicant rely on<br />

the good faith of any bank with whom the beneficiary may work without necessarily having a working<br />

relationship with that bank. There are also issues that affect negotiability where a draft is drawn on the<br />

paying bank. The paying bank would either pay or accept. The issues raised here, however, are beyond<br />

the scope of this paper.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 588 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

for purposes of determining protected status. ' The English Bills of Exchange Act<br />

does not make this distinction. It defines "value" as including "[a]ny consideration<br />

sufficient to support a simple contract."" 9 Apparently, the problem of executory<br />

promises in favor of fraudsters has not arisen in English cases or claimed the<br />

attention of the courts.<br />

As described by Ellinger, the civil law looks only to the regularity of the chain<br />

of title by which the instrument has been passed.' This approach must make aspects<br />

of the protected status under LC law confusing and explains why efforts to identify<br />

those entitled to that status have resulted in confusion.<br />

On being nominated to negotiate, a negotiating bank does not make an<br />

irrevocable commitment to negotiate under the LC. 87 With respect to letters of<br />

credit, the question to which giving value is an answer is a factor in determining<br />

whether or not there has been negotiation. The questions arise, then, whether or not<br />

and when it has purchased or given value for purposes of achieving protected status.<br />

This notion and related concepts have figured considerably in the efforts of the ICC<br />

Banking Commission to define "negotiation." At various times, it has been<br />

described as "negotiate/purchase,"" 8 "value," 89 and, once again in UCP600,<br />

"purchase." 90<br />

84. This provision is contained in the Model Uniform Commercial Code which is adopted in all fifty<br />

states with some variations. U.C.C. § 3-303(a) (2006) (stating that "[a]n instrument is issued or transferred<br />

for value if: (1) the instrument is issued or transferred for a promise of performance, to the extent the<br />

promise has been performed..."). Section 3-303(a) is based on section 54 of the predecessor statute, the<br />

Negotiable Instruments <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 7, which deviated in this respect from the U.K. Bills of Exchange<br />

Act, 1882, 45 & 46 Vict. c. 61. § 27. See also U.C.C. § 3-303, cmt. 2 (stating that "[t]he policy basis for<br />

subsection (a)(1) is that the holder who gives an executory promise of performance will not suffer an outof-pocket<br />

loss to the extent the executory promise is underperformed at the time the holder learns of<br />

dishonor of the instrument").<br />

85. Bills of Exchange Act § 27(1)(a) (Value and Holder for Value).<br />

86. ELLINGER, supra note 2, § 413.<br />

87. Where a nominated negotiating bank makes a separate undertaking to the beneficiary to negotiate<br />

drafts drawn under the letter of credit, such an undertaking is commonly (and incorrectly) described as a<br />

"silent confirmation." THE INTERNATIONAL CHAMBER OF COMMERCE, OPINIONS OF THE ICC BANKING<br />

COMMISSION 1995-1996, Resp. 207 at 27 (Gary Collyer ed., 1997) ( stating that "[slub-Article 10(c) takes<br />

note of the possibility that a nominated bank, not being a confirming bank, agrees with the beneficiary to<br />

assume a liability to pay, etc. Silent confirmation may be one of such undertakings"). UCP600 (2007)<br />

Article 12(a) also alludes to this possibility. While anticipated in UCP600 Article 12(b), which provides<br />

"[bly nominating a bank to accept a draft or incur a deferred payment undertaking, an issuing bank<br />

authorizes that nominated bank to prepay or purchase a draft accepted or a deferred payment undertaking<br />

incurred by that nominated bank," this practice is not regulated or standardized by the UCP. This<br />

undertaking is not one under the letter of credit. For more about Silent Confirmation, see Byrne, Barnes,<br />

& Maulella, Silent Confirmation (Institute of International Banking <strong>Law</strong> & Practice 2006) (Available via<br />

ON Line Replay or DVD). This topic is one that requires such extensive separate treatment that it is only<br />

tagged in this article as an area that is not included in this treatment of negotiation.<br />

88. UCP290 (1974) Article 3(a)(iii) stated:<br />

An irrevocable credit constitutes a definite undertaking of the issuing bank, provided that the<br />

terms and conditions of the credit are complied with: . . . iii to purchase/negotiate, without<br />

recourse to drawers and/or bona fide holders, drafts drawn by the beneficiary, at sight or at a<br />

tenor, on the applicant for the credit or on any other drawee specified in the credit, or to<br />

provide for purchase/negotiation by another bank, if the credit provides for<br />

purchase/negotiation.<br />

See CHARLES DEL BUSTO, UCP 500 & 400 COMPARED 29 (1993)<br />

(stating that "[n]egotiation in<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 589 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

In light of negotiable instruments law, these questions are highly confusing.<br />

Under common law, negotiation is the act of transfer by which the transferee<br />

becomes a holder. Holder in due course status is a separate question. Under the<br />

civil law, one looks to the chain of transfers to determine whether or not it has been<br />

regular on its face.<br />

There are two different perspectives in which LC negotiation is viewed.<br />

Bankers view it as an entitlement to claim reimbursement. <strong>Law</strong>yers tend to<br />

approach negotiation from the perspective of the implications of letter of credit<br />

fraud. This diverse approach is apparent with respect to "value" or "purchase."<br />

At the time UCP500 was drafted, it was thought that the reimbursement system<br />

was being abused by banks who merely examined documents and claimed<br />

reimbursement as negotiating banks without having negotiated, but merely having<br />

forwarded the documents. 9 ' The point of the UCP500 definition of negotiation as<br />

"value" was to make it clear that this practice was not proper. It soon became clear,<br />

however, that LC bankers in claiming reimbursement did not understand what was<br />

meant by "value" and, in particular, whether a promise to pay constituted value. To<br />

address the considerable concern that had been voiced, the Chair of the ICC<br />

Banking Commission issued Position Paper No. 2, which states that "'giving of value'<br />

in UCP500 Article 10(b)(ii) may be interpreted as either 'making immediate<br />

payment' (e.g., by cash, by cheque, by remittance through a Clearing System or by<br />

credit to an account) or 'undertaking an obligation to make payment' (other than<br />

giving a deferred payment undertaking or accepting a draft)." '<br />

Unsatisfied with this approach, the drafters of UCP600 defined negotiation in<br />

Article 2 (Definitions) paragraph 11 as "the purchase by the nominated bank of<br />

drafts (drawn on a bank other than the nominated bank) and/or documents under a<br />

complying presentation, by advancing or agreeing to advance funds to the<br />

beneficiary on or before the banking day on which reimbursement is due to the<br />

nominated bank." Whatever else "purchase" connotes, it does include a promise to<br />

advance funds as well as the actual advance of funds, as stated.<br />

While this redefinition solved one problem, it gave rise to another, namely<br />

whether a negotiating bank could claim a protected status in the event of beneficiary<br />

fraud as a result of a simple executory promise running to the fraudster. 93 Unless the<br />

Documentary Credit practice means more than to examine the documents. When an Issuing Bank issues a<br />

negotiation Credit, it is inviting a Nominated Bank to negotiate or to give value in exchange for a<br />

Beneficiary's draft and/or documents").<br />

89. UCP500 Article 10(b)(ii) (Types of Credit) (1994) (defining "negotiation" as "giving of value for<br />

Draft(s) and/or document(s) by the bank authorized to negotiate").<br />

90. UCP600 Article 2 (Definitions) para. 11 (2007) states:<br />

Negotiation means the purchase by the nominated bank of drafts (drawn on a bank other than<br />

the nominated bank) and/or documents under a complying presentation, by advancing or<br />

agreeing to advance funds to the beneficiary on or before the banking day on which<br />

reimbursement is due to the nominated bank.<br />

91. Signaling the concern that led to the definition, UCP500 (1983) Article 10(b)(ii) provides that<br />

"[m]ere examination of the documents without giving of value does not constitute a negotiation."<br />

92. INTERNATIONAL CHAMBER OF COMMERCE, ICC BANKING COMMISSION POSITION PAPER NO. 2,<br />

reprinted in LC RULES AND LAWS at 107 (James E. Byrne ed., 3d ed. 2004).<br />

93. There is another complicating preliminary dimension, namely that the provision in UCP600<br />

admits of two divergent readings. UCP600 Article 7(c) (Issuing Bank Undertaking) sentence 2 states that<br />

"[r]eimbursement for the amount of a complying presentation under a credit available by acceptance or<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 590 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

promise were in the form of a negotiable instrument that could be negotiated to<br />

innocent third persons or an irrevocable promise to an innocent person, the<br />

negotiating bank would have a complete excuse against a claim by the beneficiary in<br />

such a situation since fraud unravels all in every modern system of commercial law. 4<br />

In this scenario, would a court permit the negotiating bank that has not paid to<br />

recover from the issuer with a view to fulfilling in the future a promise to pay a<br />

fraudster or for fraudulent documents?<br />

The analysis is rendered more complex by the difference in common law<br />

systems with respect to whether executory promises constitute value. It may be<br />

expected that U.S. courts at least would refuse to accord protected status to a<br />

negotiating bank that merely promises to advance funds without having done so, and<br />

the same result should follow for whatever reason in other systems. On the other<br />

hand, where the negotiating bank has not yet paid but given a letter of credit to a<br />

third person or a negotiable instrument that may fall into the hands of an innocent<br />

third party, the negotiating bank has a complete defense if there is LC fraud.<br />

However it may be characterized, LC practice and law have sensed that there<br />

must be something additional to the mere transfer of the documents in order for<br />

there to be negotiation and that it must be a transfer that entitles the negotiating<br />

bank to assert rights to the documents. Such a transfer only takes place where the<br />

bank has purchased the documents in some fashion.<br />

While negotiation is typically thought of in the one-dimensional framework of a<br />

sight draft, time drafts can also be negotiated under letter of credit practice. Where<br />

a negotiating bank negotiates a time draft, it forwards the documents to the issuer or<br />

confirmer and engages in trade finance by discounting the amount due to its present<br />

value. The negotiating bank is then entitled to reimbursement at maturity. Where<br />

there is a time draft, there is always a possibility that LC fraud could be discovered<br />

or claimed in the interim period between the purchase of the draft or documents and<br />

the maturity date. In that situation, the question arises as to whether or not the<br />

negotiating bank is entitled to be reimbursed notwithstanding the fraud.<br />

This problem has been a serious difficulty with respect to deferred payment<br />

undertakings. The problem was highlighted by the English decision in Banco<br />

Santander SA v. Banque Paribas.'- Banco Santander intimated in dicta that the result<br />

deferred payment is due at maturity, whether or not the nominated bank prepaid or purchased before<br />

maturity." This sentence could mean that reimbursement is due at maturity provided that the promise to<br />

prepay or purchase was given before maturity or that the actual disbursal took place before maturity.<br />

James G. Barnes, whose suggestion lead to this provision but who was regrettably not consulted in its<br />

drafting, indicates that the latter interpretation is preferable. Some authorities, however, may interpret it<br />

in the former sense.<br />

94. The UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts (2004) Article 3.8 provides:<br />

A party may avoid the contract when it has been led to conclude the contract by the other<br />

party's fraudulent misrepresentation, including language or practices, or fraudulent nondisclosure<br />

of circumstances which, according to reasonable commercial standards of fair<br />

dealing, the latter party should have disclosed.<br />

95. See Banco Santander S.A. v. Bayfern Ltd. & Ors., [1999] 2 All E.R. (Comm.) (Q.B.) 18, affd<br />

Banco Santander SA v. Banque Paribas, [2000] 1 All E.R. (Comm.) (C.A.) 776; James G. Barnes & James<br />

E. Byrne, Letters of Credit: 2000 Cases, 56 Bus. LAW. 1805, 1813 (2001) (criticizing Banco Santander). See<br />

also Sinotani Pac. v. Ag. Bank of China, 4 S.L.R. 34 (1999); Czarnikow Rionda Sugar Trading v. Standard<br />

Bank, (1999) 2 Lloyd's Rep. (Q.B.) 187, 202; Bundesgericht [BGer] [Federal Court] June 1, 2004. 130<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 591 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

would be different had there been negotiation of a draft by a nominated negotiating<br />

bank. 96 However, a recent decision by the French Cour de Cassation concluded that<br />

under French negotiable instruments law, a confirming bank that discounted its own<br />

acceptance was not entitled to reimbursement as a protected party where letter of<br />

credit fraud had emerged after the discount and before maturity. 9 7 One would have<br />

thought that an acceptance would be entitled to a higher level of abstraction than<br />

negotiation. But then one might have thought that a confirming bank that had<br />

discounted its own confirmation would be entitled to a higher level of abstraction<br />

than a negotiating bank.<br />

In any event, UCP600 addresses this matter in three articles intended to<br />

preserve the rights of banks that discount to reimbursement." Although the term<br />

"discount" is not used, probably in order to emphasize that it is not every<br />

discounting bank, but only a nominated bank to which it applies, the terms<br />

"purchase" and "prepay" achieve the same end. 99 Under UCP600, a negotiating<br />

bank that negotiates a time draft should have added comfort with respect to its<br />

Entscheidungen des Schweizerischen Bundesgerichts [BGE] III 462 (Switz.) (for English translation, see<br />

DOCUMENTARY CREDIT WORLD, 2006 ANNUAL SURVEY at 477).<br />

96. The Banco Santander v. Bayfern Ltd. & Ors. court noted that the confirming bank's "submission<br />

was that there was no good reason why the effect of established fraud should differ in the case of<br />

acceptance credits and deferred payment credits. An acceptance credit, however, expressly involves<br />

authority from the Issuing Bank to the Confirming Bank to accept drafts and pay them at maturity,"<br />

whereas a deferred payment credit was not so authorized. Banco Satander, 2 All E.R. (Comm.)(Q.B.) 18.<br />

97. See Cour de cassation [highest court of ordinary jurisdiction] Cass. com., Oct. 11, 2005, Bull. civ,<br />

IV, No. 1246 (Fr.). See also Jean Stoufflet, May a Bank Contest the Authenticity of Documents After<br />

Accepting the Beneficiary's Draft and Refuse Payment of a Documentary Credit?, in DOCUMENTARY<br />

CREDIT WORLD, Feb. 2006, at 12.<br />

98. In addition to the definition of "Negotiation" in UCP600 Article 2 paragraph 11, Articles 7(c)<br />

(Issuing Bank Undertaking) and 8(c) (Confirming Bank Undertaking) address reimbursement of<br />

nominating banks. UCP600 Article 8(c), for example, states:<br />

A confirming bank undertakes to reimburse another nominated bank that has honoured or<br />

negotiated a complying presentation and forwarded the documents to the confirming bank.<br />

Reimbursement for the amount of a complying presentation under a credit available by<br />

acceptance or deferred payment is due at maturity, whether or not another nominated<br />

bank prepaid or purchased before maturity. A confirming bank's undertaking to reimburse<br />

another nominated bank is independent of the confirming bank's undertaking to the<br />

beneficiary.<br />

99. UCP600 (2007) Article 12(b) (Nomination) states that nomination of a bank to incur a deferred<br />

payment undertaking or to accept authorizes that bank "to prepay or purchase a draft accepted or a<br />

deferred payment undertaking incurred by that nominated bank." Although not explained, "prepay" and<br />

"purchase" are quite different in their meaning and implications. While a bank can purchase a draft or<br />

documents presented under an LC whether or not it is nominated and whether or not it is obligated on an<br />

LC, only a bank that is obligated can prepay its own obligation because prepayment signifies discharge of<br />

the obligation whereas an obligation that is purchased is not discharged by the purchase. A further step is<br />

required to discharge the obligation. While negotiation without recourse by a confirming bank discharges<br />

its obligation under a letter of credit, it is not "prepayment" because negotiation occurs when the<br />

documents are presented and negotiation is not a prepayment. That the negotiation is in advance of the<br />

time when reimbursement is due does not constitute "prepayment" for purposes of UCP600. The term<br />

"purchase" is further explained in the UCP600 Article 2 paragraph 11 definition of negotiation by the term<br />

"advance," which occurs "by advancing or agreeing to advance funds to the beneficiary on or before the<br />

banking day on which reimbursement is due to the nominated bank." "Advance" connotes a temporal<br />

relationship to something it precedes, namely the reimbursement by an issuer or confirmer. The addition<br />

of the phrase limiting the time within which the advance must occur indicates that negotiation may not<br />

occur after reimbursement is due. What it does not clarify is whether or not the actual advance of funds<br />

must have occurred by the time that reimbursement is due.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 592 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

entitlement to reimbursement in the event of intervening discovery of letter of credit<br />

fraud.<br />

6. Notice<br />

Since negotiating banks have not made any irrevocable undertaking to honor<br />

under the letter of credit, an allegation of fraud of which they have notice operates<br />

differently on them than it would on an issuer or confirmer. A bank has not duly<br />

negotiated if it has notice of letter of credit fraud prior to negotiating. While a mere<br />

accusation of LC fraud subsequent to the issuance or confirmation of the credit will<br />

not defeat the right of an issuer or confirmer to reimbursement since they are<br />

obligated to pay, a negotiating bank that has no irrevocable letter of credit<br />

obligation can refuse to negotiate if notified before it does so and bears the risk if<br />

LC fraud is proven. On the other hand, notice of LC fraud after the negotiating<br />

bank duly negotiates does not affect its status.' 00<br />

IV. TOWARDS A DEFINITION OF LC NEGOTIATION<br />

The UCP600 Article 2 (Definitions) paragraph 11 definition of negotiation<br />

suffers from the problems of the general UCP600 approach to definitions and<br />

drafting, namely the use of interlocking definitions and the avoidance of substance.<br />

With respect to the concept of negotiation, at least, the fault cannot be attributed to<br />

the drafters. The ICC Banking Commission is constitutionally incapable of<br />

addressing such serious doctrinal issues in a coherent manner. Being fundamentally<br />

a political body, it is only able to endorse a solution that has achieved consensus<br />

among controlling political interests. No such preparatory work has been done with<br />

respect to negotiation. Therefore, the "solution" to problems is to shuffle words.<br />

One of the problems in understanding negotiation in LC practice is the<br />

tendency to place too much emphasis on the term "negotiation" and the conceptual<br />

and political inability of bankers to address problems of letter of credit fraud in a<br />

coherent and objective manner. Negotiation in negotiable instruments law is merely<br />

the transfer of a negotiable instrument in such a manner that the transferee becomes<br />

the person entitled to exercise special rights under the instrument as its "holder" in<br />

the law of negotiable instruments.<br />

In letter of credit practice, when there is negotiation by a nominated<br />

negotiating bank, it is the right to be paid the proceeds under the LC that is<br />

transferred to the negotiating bank in its own right as the entity entitled to the<br />

proceeds under the LC. The transfer involved is similar to the transfer of drawing<br />

rights in that it is to be distinguished from a mere assignment of proceeds.' Because<br />

a letter of credit is a "special" undertaking in that it runs only to the named<br />

beneficiary, the right to draw or perform is restricted to the named entity, although<br />

100. To the extent that the value given by the negotiating bank is executory, a possible issue arises.<br />

See supra note 84.<br />

101. Unlike the general law of consensual obligations, "transfer" and "assignment" are distinguished<br />

in letter of credit practice and law. See UCP600 (2007) Articles 38 (Transferable Credits) and 39<br />

(Assignment of Proceeds); ISP98, supra note 10, Rule 6 (Transfer, Assignment, and Transfer by Operation<br />

of <strong>Law</strong>); G.A. Res. 50/48, supra note 58,_arts. 9-10; Revised U.C.C. §§ 5-112-5-114.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 593 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:561<br />

payment-as opposed to performance-is less rigidly controlled. There are<br />

important practical reasons for this limitation. As a documentary undertaking<br />

involving payment against representations, neither the applicant nor the issuer want<br />

to incur the risk of performance by a stranger to the underlying transaction absent<br />

their express permission.<br />

Although less clearly appreciated, the same principle applies to payment of the<br />

proceeds of a letter of credit. A mere LC assignment does not confer a right to the<br />

proceeds, but a transfer does. Yet a transfer is not the only mode by which the right<br />

to proceeds can be conveyed.<br />

Absent a transfer to it, the negotiating bank cannot perform under the credit.<br />

But once there is performance, a negotiating bank that has duly negotiated has a<br />

separate independent right to the proceeds being paid to it in its own name and not<br />

as an assignee of the beneficiary. In effect, LC negotiation is the transfer of the right<br />

to the proceeds of the LC.<br />

Unlike the transferee beneficiary, the negotiating bank is not automatically<br />

entitled to an independent status from the beneficiary; it must have negotiated for<br />

value, in good faith, and with no notice of the LC fraud. Unlike a LC transfer of<br />

drawing rights, the negotiating bank is not entitled to draw in its own name, only to<br />

receive the proceeds in its own name. In this sense, negotiation can be understood<br />

as the transfer (as opposed to LC "assignment") of the right to proceeds. 12 Whether<br />

the negotiating bank, when it is the transferee of proceeds, is entitled to them in the<br />

face of beneficiary LC fraud depends on the answer to a different question, namely<br />

its bona fide status.<br />

V. CONCLUSION<br />

This paper lists and identifies detailed technical differences between<br />

negotiation with respect to negotiable instruments and negotiation with respect to<br />

letters of credit. These differences are substantial and themselves warrant the<br />

conclusion that the law of negotiable instruments is inadequate as a basis for<br />

governing issues with respect to negotiable instruments presented under letters of<br />

credit.<br />

This paper follows the evolution of the letter of credit from an appendage of<br />

negotiable instrument law to a separate system in its own right with some remaining<br />

vestiges of negotiable instrument law, albeit in new guise. In one sense, the various<br />

matters discussed are elementary. In another sense, comparison between them and<br />

analysis of their differences and their significance is challenging. This paper does not<br />

claim to be a definitive or systematic study of this area, but is intended to provoke<br />

further efforts that will hopefully lead to such a study.<br />

One of its themes is that letter of credit practice and law have evolved as a<br />

separate legal discipline. As a result, letter of credit law has become decoupled from<br />

the law of negotiable instruments. Where a negotiable instrument is involved, there<br />

may be another cause of action or theory of liability or available recovery-in<br />

102. This approach elects not to frame the question in terms of reimbursement rights. That<br />

appellation is appropriate for entities that are obligated on the LC such as the confirmer or issuer. It is<br />

also appropriate for a paying bank. It is less so for a negotiating bank, which retains its right of recourse<br />

and acts more independently than do the other nominated banks.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 594 2006-2007


2007<br />

NEGOTIATION IN LETTER OF CREDIT PRACTICE AND LAW<br />

addition to that under letter of credit law-but the two are separate and distinct<br />

areas of law.<br />

The failure to recognize the existence in letters of credit of a system that is<br />

parallel, different, and separate from that of negotiable instruments will lead to<br />

confusion and defeat the reasonable expectations of the commercial community.<br />

This result has been apparent in cases regarding acceptances arising under letters of<br />

credit where a rigid interpretation of the abstract character of an acceptance led the<br />

court to the conclusion that payment must be made to a fraudster simply because of<br />

the existence of the acceptance.' 3 This approach results in bad policy, not only with<br />

respect to letters of credit, but also with respect to negotiable instruments.<br />

The attraction of negotiable instruments law as a means of resolving letter of<br />

credit issues is, in part, that it represents a codified body of law and, also in part, that<br />

lawyers and judges are familiar with it-whereas in many countries, letter of credit<br />

law is not codified, and most lawyers and judges are not familiar with it. As a result,<br />

it becomes easy to apply the highly technical rules of negotiable instruments as a<br />

means of reaching a decision in cases involving letters of credit without delving into<br />

the policies which underlie these rules and the appropriateness of their application to<br />

a problem involving letters of credit. Without a clear understanding of the policy<br />

behind rules, however, it is no longer possible to apply rules in an intelligent manner<br />

because it becomes impossible to determine when the rule ceases to achieve the end<br />

for which it is designed.<br />

Under letters of credit, the undertaking embodied in the letter of credit extends<br />

beyond bringing into existence a draft to be presented. While there may be a<br />

separate set of obligations which arise with respect to the draft, even where it has<br />

been accepted, there remain in place obligations concerning the letter of credit<br />

undertaking that are not subsumed by the acceptance. Indeed, where there is a<br />

conflict, it is the letter of credit obligation that subsumes that which arises with<br />

respect to the draft.' "<br />

There is, however, a further point to which attention should be drawn. The<br />

letter of credit takes the concept of negotiability beyond that which is achieved<br />

under the regime of negotiable instruments. Negotiable instruments shackle the<br />

concept of negotiability to the paper with which it is merged, and for historical<br />

reasons, immerse it in formal and technical rules. While it may be necessary that a<br />

general instrument of debt and credit be surrounded by such technicalities, it is not<br />

inevitable. Indeed, an equivalent level of abstractness has been achieved at least in<br />

U.S. commercial law with respect to leases of personal property and their hell-orhigh-water<br />

clauses'"" and security interests in personal property, whereby an<br />

assignment can be given the effect otherwise achieved by a negotiable instrument. ' 6°<br />

With letters of credit, however, a higher degree of negotiability has been<br />

achieved. In this sense, negotiability consists of a free transfer of obligations without<br />

or with limited encumbrances. Letters of credit have thus achieved a relatively high<br />

103. See All Services Exportacao, lmportacao Comercia v. Banco Bamerindus Do Brazil, 921 F.2d 32,<br />

35-36 (2d Cir. 1990); First Commercial Bank v. Gotham Originals, Inc., 475 N.E.2d 1255, 1260 (N.Y. 1985).<br />

104. U.C.C. § 5-116(d) (2006).<br />

105. See, e.g., U.C.C. § 2A-407 (Irrevocable Promises: Finance Leases).<br />

106. See Revised U.C.C. § 9-403 (revised 2000) (Agreement Not to Assert Defenses Against<br />

Assignee).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 595 2006-2007


596 TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL VOL. 42:561<br />

form of liquidity. In particular, in the form of standby letters of credit, they have<br />

achieved an incomparable level of liquidity-coupled with flexibility in an<br />

instrument whose integrity has, on the whole, not been diminished. This remarkable<br />

achievement, having arisen historically and conceptually from the doctrine of<br />

negotiability, has become a central feature of letter of credit practice and law.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 596 2006-2007


Theorizing Transnational Commercial <strong>Law</strong><br />

Ross CRANSTON*<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. G LO BA LISA TIO N ................................................................................................. 600<br />

II. THE RULE OF LAW AND ITS CONSEQUENCES .................................................. 607<br />

III. THE POW ER OF THE M ARKET ............................................................................ 610<br />

IV. IMPLEMENTING THE NEW TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW ................. 614<br />

V . C O N C LU SIO N ....................................................................................................... 616<br />

Over recent decades we can see the emergence of a new transnational<br />

commercial law. It consists of international conventions, model laws, and statements<br />

of principle (or standards). A recent compilation consists of some sixty instruments<br />

divided into twelve subject areas as diverse as contract law, electronic commerce,<br />

sales, agency and distribution, international credit transfers and bank payment<br />

undertakings, secured transactions, cross-border insolvency, conflict of laws,<br />

international civil procedure, and international commercial arbitration.' Even this<br />

comprehensive collection is not exhaustive, as will be evident from later discussion.<br />

The new transnational commercial law is driven by international institutions<br />

ranging from UNCITRAL, UNIDROIT, and the World Bank; regional<br />

governmental or economic bodies like the European Union or MERCOSUR;<br />

specialist international bodies such as the Basel Committees on Banking Supervision<br />

and Payment and Settlement Systems, and the International Organization of<br />

Securities Commissions (IOSCO); and industry bodies such as the International<br />

Chamber of Commerce (ICC).' There is a great deal of overlap in the application of<br />

their work in practice. Take, for instance, the area of transnational financial law: the<br />

* QC; Centennial Professor of <strong>Law</strong>, London School of Economics and Political Science. President,<br />

International Academy of Commercial and Consumer law, 2004-2006. This paper draws to an extent on<br />

How <strong>Law</strong> Works (Oxford, 2006) and has benefited from being presented in various guises at the National<br />

<strong>Law</strong> School, Bangalore, India, and the National Autonomous University of Mexico, Mexico City.<br />

1. E.g., ROY GOODE, ET AL., TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW: INTERNATIONAL INSTRUMENTS<br />

AND COMMENTARY at v (2004); see Gbenga Bamodu, Extra-national Legal Principles in the Global Village:<br />

A Conceptual Examination of Transnational <strong>Law</strong>, 7 INT'L ARB. L. REV. 6 (2001).<br />

2. E.g., UNIDROIT 75 "h Anniversary Congress on Worldwide Harmonisation of Private <strong>Law</strong> and<br />

Regional Economic Integration, I UNIFORM L.REV. 1ff. (2003).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 597 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:597<br />

Financial Stability Forum brings together national authorities responsible for<br />

financial stability around the world. In order to further its aims, the Forum advances<br />

a compendium of twelve key standards concerning transparency of policy making in<br />

the financial system, sound institutional and market infrastructure, and adequate<br />

financial regulation.' The standards are drawn from a range of international bodies,<br />

including the International Monetary Fund (standards on macroeconomic policy and<br />

data transparency), the World Bank (insolvency and credit guidelines), Organisation<br />

for Economic Co-operation and Development (principles of corporate governance),<br />

the Basel Committee, IOSCO, and Financial Action Task Force on Money<br />

Laundering. As well as providing a fine overview of the area, Professor Mario<br />

Giovanoli has argued that the new transnational financial law is mainly stand-alone<br />

"soft law," independent of any international framework of binding legal rules and<br />

sometimes lacking the degree of precision indispensable to a legally enforceable<br />

rule. 4 In addition to classifying the new transnational commercial law according to its<br />

subject matter or institutional source, one may classify it by the juridical nature of<br />

the instrument. Thus it is possible to divide transnational commercial law into<br />

principles (or standards), model laws, and international conventions. A very longstanding<br />

set of principles is the Uniform Customs and Practice for Documentary<br />

Credits, first published by the ICC in 1933. However, such principles of<br />

transnational commercial law extend well beyond trade. The well known<br />

UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts are mentioned at<br />

greater length below.' The standards collected by the Financial Stability Forum have<br />

been referred to. In the area of dispute settlement there are the ALI/UNIDROIT<br />

Principles of Transnational Civil Procedure.' The lex mecatoria is more difficult to<br />

identify, as we shall see, but it consists of principles like good faith, reasonableness,<br />

the duty to negotiate, set-off, and the obligation to compensate on expropriation.<br />

Among the model laws of transnational commercial law-a second category of<br />

instrument-are those of UNCITRAL, which now has Model <strong>Law</strong>s on International<br />

Commercial Arbitration, Cross-Border Insolvency, and International Credit<br />

Transfers. 7 The model laws used by bodies like the World Bank and IMF in their<br />

technical assistance work are not always publicly available nor are records of which<br />

countries have adopted them and in what form. In effect, these World Bank Model<br />

<strong>Law</strong>s extend beyond the financial sector to matters such as insolvency and security.<br />

As to international conventions relating to transnational commercial law, these<br />

began in the first part of the twentieth century. To take just the financial area,<br />

conventions were drawn up for a Uniform <strong>Law</strong> on Bills of Exchange and Promissory<br />

3. Financial Stability Forum, www.fsforum.org; see also THE ROAD TO INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL<br />

STABILITY: ARE KEY FINANCIAL STANDARDS THE ANSWER? (Benu Schneider ed., 2003).<br />

4. Mario Giovanoli, A New Architecture for the Global Financial Market: Legal Aspects of<br />

International Financial Standard Setting, in INTERNATIONAL MONETARY LAW, 40 (Mario Giovanoli ed.,<br />

2000).<br />

5. Michael J. Bonell, The UNIDROIT Principles and Transnational <strong>Law</strong>, 2 Uniform L. Rev. 199<br />

(2000); Juirgen Basedow, Uniform <strong>Law</strong> Conventions and the UNIDROIT Principles of International<br />

Commercial Contracts, 1 UNIFORM L. REV. 129 (2000).<br />

6. American <strong>Law</strong> Institute & UNIDROIT, ALI/UNIDROIT Principles of Transnational Civil<br />

Procedure xxix (2006).<br />

7. The first-mentioned has been adopted by over fifty states: Pieter Sanders, UNCITRAL's Model<br />

<strong>Law</strong> on International and Commercial Arbitration: Present Situation and Future, 21 ARB. INT'L 443 (2005).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 598 2006-2007


2007<br />

THEORIZING TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW<br />

Notes and a Uniform <strong>Law</strong> Concerning Cheques. International conventions from<br />

recent decades include the United Nations Convention on Contracts for the<br />

International Sale of Goods (CISG) (1980)', the Convention on the Recognition and<br />

Enforcement of Foreign Arbitral Awards (the New York Convention) (1958)0o and<br />

the United Nations Convention on the Assignment of Receivables in International<br />

Trade (2001)."<br />

It is possible to explore how these different types of instrument are given force.<br />

First, uniform principles have effect in as much as they are consciously invoked by<br />

parties engaged in international transactions (primarily by incorporation by<br />

reference in their contracts) or by those settling disputes between such parties<br />

(primarily arbitrators). Thus, the Uniform Customs and Practice for Documentary<br />

Credits are widely incorporated by international banks in the letters of credit they<br />

issue. Although the confidentiality of arbitration proceedings makes it difficult to be<br />

definite about the matter, it seems that international arbitrators are making<br />

increasing reference, if only informally, to the UNIDROIT Principles of<br />

International Commercial Contracts. Secondly, as the name suggests, a model law is<br />

designed for adoption by national legislatures. While it is not always easy to<br />

determine whether a model law has been adopted since it may be dressed up as local<br />

law reform, it is evident that the UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong> on Cross-Border<br />

Insolvency is being widely implemented. Thirdly, a convention is a treaty, to which<br />

states can choose to be a party. Model laws can obviously be modified in their<br />

adoption or adopted in part, whereas parties to a convention must enter reservations<br />

if there are to be departures from it. The New York Convention has had almost<br />

universal success and is one explanation for the popularity of international<br />

commercial arbitration - by contrast to the situation with foreign court judgments,<br />

almost every country is committed to enforcing foreign arbitral awards.<br />

The purpose of this essay is not so much to describe the institutions or to<br />

analyse the substantive provisions of the new transnational commercial law. Rather<br />

what this essay explores is whether it can be said that there is any legal theory which<br />

helps explain the emergence of this new transnational commercial law and its<br />

adoption by national systems. This essay suggests that there are several bodies of<br />

legal theory which throw light on these two issues. The first uses globalisation as an<br />

explanatory factor. It arises in particular in accounts of the new lex mecatoria and<br />

also in explanations of the emergence of the uniform principles, model laws, and<br />

international conventions drawn up under the auspices of bodies such as<br />

UNCITRAL, UNIDROIT, the World Bank, and the ICC. A second is rule of law<br />

8. Manley 0. Hudson & Abraham H. Feller, The International Unification of <strong>Law</strong>s Concerning Bills<br />

of Exchange 44 HARV. L. REV. 333, 333-34 (1931); Abraham H. Feller, The International Unification of<br />

<strong>Law</strong>s Concerning Checks 45 HARV. L. REV. 668, 668 (1932); see also the so-called Hague Rules - the<br />

International Convention for the Unification of Certain Rules of <strong>Law</strong> Relating to Bills of Lading (Brussels,<br />

1924); Jirgen Basedow, Global Life, Local <strong>Law</strong>? in LIBER AMICORUM EN HOMENAJE AL PROFESSOR DR.<br />

DIDIER OPERTI BASTAN 825-26 (2005).<br />

9. United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods, Apr. 10, 1980, 1489<br />

U.N.T.S. 3, available at http://www.uncitral.org/en-index.htm.<br />

10. United Nations Convention on the Recognition and Enforcement of Foreign Arbitral Awards,<br />

June 10, t958, 21 U.S.T. 2517, 330 U.N.T.S. 38.<br />

11. United Nations Convention on the Assignment of Receivables in International Trade, G.A. Res.<br />

56/81, U.N. GAOR, 56th Sess., U.N. Doc. A/RES/56/81 (Dec. 12, 2001), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/english/texts/payments/receivables/ctc-assignment-convention-e.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 599 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:597<br />

theory, which is especially popular with the World Bank and related bodies like the<br />

IMF. According to this strand of thinking, economic development demands a legal<br />

system which protects contractual and property rights both in terms of substantive<br />

rules and judicial administration. A legal system built on the rule of law is said to do<br />

this. One aspect of the rule of law is a substantive law which reflects the principles of<br />

the new transnational commercial law. A third body of theory plays to market<br />

forces. Countries fall along a spectrum from pro-creditor to pro-debtor in terms of<br />

their commercial laws. Where countries are on the spectrum turns in part on<br />

whether they have adopted the legal standards, codes, and principles of the new<br />

transnational commercial law. Whether a country is pro-creditor or pro-debtor feeds<br />

into market assessments of its economy and that influences the behaviour of foreign<br />

investors. Finally, there is the theory which helps explain the adoption of the<br />

conventions, model laws, and standards. One aspect of this is whether the legal<br />

principles incorporated in them have resonance with legal practitioners and<br />

institutions so that they use them to structure commercial transactions. Another<br />

aspect is legal transplant theory, which bears on whether these codes and standards<br />

are implemented by national legislation. Legal transplant theory is only part of the<br />

explanation for successful adoptions, for, as we will see, there must also be the<br />

political will within each jurisdiction to enact these into law.<br />

I. GLOBALISATION<br />

Globalisation is a slippery concept but encompasses objective developments in<br />

the economic, cultural, political, and technological spheres. 12 People's consciousness<br />

about the phenomenon is as important as these objective developments. That<br />

sometimes leads to resistance to what globalisation entails. In some contexts,<br />

globalisation is being used to describe a process of social change, a world being<br />

transformed so that there are greater contacts across national boundaries and growth<br />

or intensification 'of new networks and interdependencies. In other contexts-it<br />

means the condition where geographical boundaries are rendered less relevant by<br />

the existence of these cross-border connections and arrangements. Globalisation<br />

gives rise to apparent paradoxes. The fact that globalisation is multidimensional<br />

makes it all the more difficult to analyze. Depending on how it is defined, the<br />

globalisation label may be applied to eras earlier than our own. 13 Those dedicated to<br />

resisting globalisation often use its products, such as global communications and<br />

media outlets, to further their aims.<br />

For the purposes of analysing the new transnational commercial law we can<br />

ignore the complexities and paradoxes of globalisation. Our focus is mainly its<br />

economic dimension. In this regard, globalisation is largely confined to international<br />

trade and financial markets and often does not implicate multinational institutions<br />

such as the North America Free Trade Area or the European Community. The<br />

global economic order we are interested in takes its form in the huge flows of goods,<br />

services, and capital around the world." The international nature of trade and the<br />

12. ANTHONY GIDDENS, RUNAWAY WORLD (2000); DAVID HELD ET AL., GLOBAL<br />

TRANSFORMATIONS 1 (1999); THE GLOBALIZATION READER 1 (Frank Lechner & John Boli eds., 2000).<br />

13. E.g., Ross Cranston, Globalisation: Its Historical Context, in COMMERCIAL LAW AND<br />

COMMERCIAL PRACTICE 3-4 (Sarah Worthington ed., 2003).<br />

14. See, e.g., GLOBAL CAPITALISM (Will Hutton & Anthony Giddens eds., 2000); ROBERT GILPIN,<br />

GLOBAL POLITICAL ECONOMY (2001).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 600 2006-2007


2007<br />

THEORIZING TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW<br />

liberalisation of financial transactions have created an enhanced role for the<br />

international institutions identified earlier. These bodies have promoted the<br />

harmonized rules which constitute the new transnational commercial law to channel<br />

and govern international trade and financial transactions. As the World Bank has<br />

put it:<br />

Beyond reducing transaction costs, adoption of international standards can<br />

also facilitate domestic policy reform when local interest groups have<br />

conflicting preferences. Adoption of international standards can also<br />

signal to firms, consumers, and other groups the application of high<br />

regulatory standards. The tensions between local customization and<br />

international harmonization play out in proposals to develop common<br />

international rules and standards on a wide range of issues relevant to the<br />

investment climate. Efforts to develop uniform standards to ease<br />

international commerce have long been a focus of private bodies such as<br />

the International Chamber of Commerce. Complementary efforts at the<br />

intergovernmental level include those of the United Nations Commission<br />

on International Trade <strong>Law</strong> (UNCITRAL) and a variety of other<br />

international agencies.'"<br />

So, in this analysis, globalisation means international commerce, which in turn<br />

demands facilitative law, and this, it is said, is best derived from the new<br />

transnational commercial law, itself a product of globalisation.<br />

Those invoking globalisation as an explanation for the new transnational<br />

commercial law frequently draw inspiration from the medieval lex mercatoria, which<br />

evolved from the practices of the merchants as they traded at international trade<br />

fairs, held in the great medieval cities and ports of Europe. It was globalisation and<br />

globalised law, but in a different era. Berman provides an account of the<br />

development of what "came to be viewed as an integrated, developing system, a<br />

6<br />

body of law.' In his analysis it was a consequence of the enormous social and<br />

economic transformation which Europe underwent from the late eleventh and<br />

twelfth centuries." Its principles began initially with the merchants themselves, in<br />

the mercantile courts they founded.' Later, the principles spread.' 9 Some were<br />

compiled into codes of mercantile practice; in other instances, the mercantile courts<br />

themselves kept records of their decisions, which could be used in subsequent cases.<br />

Additionally, documents like bills of exchange and bills of lading, designed for<br />

particular transactions, circulated widely. 20 Among the distinctive characteristics of<br />

European mercantile law which Berman identifies are: 1) the distinctions between<br />

real and personal property and between ownership and possession; 2) the creation of<br />

security interests in personal property; 3) the recognition of the rights of the goodfaith<br />

purchaser of goods and bills of exchange; 4) the creation of documents, such as<br />

15. World Bank, World Development Report 2005: A Better Investment Climate for Everyone 181<br />

(2004).<br />

16. HAROLD BERMAN, LAW AND REVOLUTION: THE FORMATION OF THE WESTERN LEGAL<br />

TRADITION 333 (1983).<br />

17. Id. (emphasis omitted).<br />

18. See id. at 333-56.<br />

19. See id.<br />

20. See id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 601 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:597<br />

negotiable instruments and bills of lading, which embodied rights distinct from any<br />

underlying transaction; and 5) the development of new business forms such as<br />

partnership and the commenda (which he describes as a kind of joint stock company,<br />

with the liability of each investor limited). 2 ' Ultimately this medieval lex mercatoria<br />

lost its international character as it was incorporated into domestic law. In English<br />

conventional wisdom, this was a happy process because of the role of Lord<br />

Mansfield. 22<br />

The notion of a medieval lex mercatoria-globalised, objective, and based on a<br />

reciprocity of rights between the parties-does not bear close scrutiny. One form of<br />

criticism is that the lex mercatoria was never completely divorced from state power.<br />

In theoretical terms, this was because whatever independent merchants might want<br />

in regulating the terms of trade, they needed the rule of law administered by a<br />

national legal system to protect the market from the local ruler's whim. However<br />

desirable an independent mercantile law might be, merchants had to accept a<br />

second-best solution where mercantile and state law were fused in national courts. 23<br />

In historical terms, despite a widespread belief in its existence, a general lex<br />

mercatoria is not easy to uncover. 4 There are examples of merchants winning some<br />

privileges from the exercise of state power. For example, in England there were<br />

separate procedures for mercantile disputes apart from the common law courts; thus,<br />

shipping cases were handled by the separate Admiralty Court." However, until the<br />

great constitutional struggles of the seventeenth century, the lex mercatoria as used<br />

in England was apparently not a term describing a body of substantive law; rather, it<br />

stood for the separate judicial procedure for settling mercantile disputes. 26 The<br />

distinct principles of mercantile law which existed for shipping and trade were far<br />

from universal-the various maritime laws of Europe provided different solutions to<br />

the same problems. As Cordes argues, "Lord Mansfield's 'one and the same law'<br />

that according to him existed in all countries and at all times in an identical form did<br />

not exist even in the field of the maritime law of freight," which was quintessentially<br />

an area where it should have. 27 The body of transnational rules of law as postulated<br />

in the lex mercatoria can be detected only by choosing to focus on overly general<br />

issues."<br />

21. Id. at 349-50.<br />

22. E.g., Thomas E. Scrutton [one of England's great commercial judges], A General Survey of the<br />

History of the <strong>Law</strong> Merchant, in 3 SELECT ESSAYS IN ANGLO-AMERICAN LEGAL HISTORY (1909), J.H.<br />

Baker, The <strong>Law</strong> Merchant and the Common <strong>Law</strong> Before 1700, 38 CAMBRIDGE L.J. 295 (1979); JAMES<br />

OLDHAM, ENGLISH COMMON LAW IN THE AGE OF MANSFIELD 124 (2004); Christopher P. Rodgers,<br />

Continental Literature and the Development of the Common <strong>Law</strong> by the King's Bench: c 1750-1800, in THE<br />

COURTS AND THE DEVELOPMENT OF COMMERCIAL LAW 162 (Vito Piergiovanni ed., 1987); see MICHAEL<br />

LOBBAN, THE COMMON LAW AND ENGLISH JURISPRUDENCE 1760-1850, 109 (1991).<br />

23. ROBERTO UNGER, LAW IN MODERN SOCIETY 73-76 (1976).<br />

24. Oliver Volckart & Antje Mangels, Are the Roots of the Modern Lex Mercatoria Really Medieval?<br />

65 S. ECON. J. 427, 435-46 (1999).<br />

25. HENRY J. BOURGUIGNON, SIR WILLIAM SCOTr, LORD STOWELL, JUDE OF THE HIGH COURT OF<br />

ADMIRALTY 1798-1828 5-6, 59-60 (1987).<br />

26. GERARD MALYNES, LEX MERCATORIA OR THE ANCIENT LAW MERCHANT (1622) may be seen<br />

in the context of these struggles.<br />

27. Albrecht Cordes, The Search for a Medieval Lex Mercatoria, 5 OXFORD U. COMP. L. FORUM 9, at<br />

http://ouclf.iuscomp.org/articles/cordes.shtml (2003).<br />

28. See id.; Emily Kadens, Order Within <strong>Law</strong>, Variety Within Custom: The Character of the Medieval<br />

Merchant <strong>Law</strong>, 5 CHI. J. INT'L. L. 39, 40-41, 56 (2004).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 602 2006-2007


2007<br />

THEORIZING TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW<br />

The importance of this for present purposes is that, as with commercial law in<br />

medieval times, globalisation may not provide a complete explanation of the new<br />

transnational commercial law. Certainly advocates of a modern lex mecatoria see a<br />

definite continuity with the medieval law merchant or at least an inspiration to be<br />

derived from it. 29 One of the most effective English proponents of the new lex<br />

mecatoria was Professor Clive Schmitthoff. Schmitthoff argued that international<br />

trade law developed in three stages - the medieval lex mercatoria, the period of its<br />

incorporation into national legal systems, and the modern period. He saw the third<br />

phase as a conscious and deliberate return to the international spirit of the medieval<br />

lex mercatoria. In this view the new lex mercatoria is global. Schmitthoff rejects the<br />

second, national phase of international trade law where the lawyer must resort to<br />

national rules in the conflict of laws to discover the law that is governing the<br />

contract. That was an attempt at localising an international relationship in a national<br />

legal setting, an approach modern thinking rejected. In Schmitthoff's view modern<br />

trade demanded an autonomous international trade law, founded on uniform rules<br />

accepted in all countries, making the localisation of a transaction in a national<br />

jurisdiction superfluous. This would be "a new lex mercatoria. ' 3 , 0 While Schmitthoff's<br />

views had been anticipated by others such as Berthold Goldman, 3 ' it was he who<br />

gave academic respectability to the idea in the English speaking world. 2<br />

A variety of scholars have taken up the cudgels for the new lex mercatoria.<br />

Perhaps the most active proponent today of a new lex mercatoria is Dr. Peter Berger<br />

of the Center for Transnational <strong>Law</strong> (CENTRAL) at the University of Cologne. In<br />

his book The Creeping Codification of the Lex Mercatoria, Berger argues that the<br />

concepts of transnational commercial law already used in contract drafting and<br />

dispute resolution are now being transformed into concrete principles. 3 The<br />

UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts are an example?<br />

Berger argues that the process is gradual-the lex mercatoria is living law-and that<br />

the result comes not from above through formal codification but from below through<br />

the private work of academics and practitioners." Thus, the new lex mercatoria is a<br />

response to the commercial demands of globalisation. Based on Professor Berger's<br />

discussion in Creeping Codification, CENTRAL now has an impressive collection of<br />

29. LEON E. TRAKMAN, THE LAW MERCHANT: THE EVOLUTION OF COMMERCIAL LAW 30-40<br />

(1983).<br />

30. CLIVE M. SCHMITTHOFF, COMMERCIAL LAW IN A CHANGING ECONOMIC CLIMATE 20 (2d ed.<br />

1981); see generally J(rgen Basedow, The Effects of Globalization on Private International <strong>Law</strong>, in LEGAL<br />

ASPECTS OF GLOBALIZATION (Jargen Basedow & Toshyuiki Kono eds., 2000).<br />

31. E.g,. Berthold Goldman, "Frontires du Droit et Lex Mercatoria," Archives de Philosophie du<br />

Droit, 1964, 177; see also Berthold Goldman, The Applicable <strong>Law</strong>: General Principles of <strong>Law</strong> - The Lex<br />

Mercatoria. in CONTEMPORARY PROBLEMS IN INTERNATIONAL ARBITRATION 114-16 (Julian Lew ed.,<br />

1987): Aleksander Goldstajn, The New <strong>Law</strong> Merchant, 1961 J. BUS. L. 12. 12. 17 (1961).<br />

32. See John Adams, Clive Macmillan Schmitthoff (1903-1990), in JURISTS UPROOTED; GERMAN-<br />

SPEAKING EMIGRt LAWYERS IN TWENTIETH CENTURY BRITAIN (Jack Beatson & Reinhard<br />

Zimmermann eds., 2004); THE SOURCES OF THE LAW OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE 374-76 (Clive<br />

Scmitthoff ed., 1964).<br />

33. KLAUS P. BERGER, THE CREEPING CODIFICATION OF THE LEX MERCATORIA (1998).<br />

34. M. Bonell, Do We Need a Global Commercial Code? 106 DICK. L. REV. 87, 98-99 (2001); see<br />

generally PRINCIPLES OF EUROPEAN CONTRACT LAW PARTS I AND II xxi-xxvii (Ole Lando & Hugh Beale<br />

eds., 2000); http://www.unilex.info/dynasite.cfm?dssid=2377&dsmid=13618&x=l. (The UNILEX website<br />

lists only twenty-three cases where the UNIDROIT principles have been cited as of March 1, 2006.)<br />

35. BERGER, supra note 33, at 210-11; Jeremy K. Sharpe, The Creeping Codification of Transnational<br />

Commercial <strong>Law</strong>: An Arbitrator's Perspective, 45 VA. J. INT'L L. 199 (2001).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 603 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:597<br />

lex mercatoria principles, rules, and standards. 3 6 These are divided into fifteen<br />

chapters, including chapters on good faith, reasonableness, the duty to negotiate,<br />

damages for breach of contract, set-off, unjust enrichment, and the duty to<br />

compensate on expropriation. Each principle is supported by detailed references to<br />

scholarly writings, court decisions, arbitration awards, international conventions, and<br />

national laws. 37<br />

International commercial arbitration has been seen by some as the key avenue<br />

for the enunciation of the substantive rules of the new lex mercatoria." Its growth is<br />

partly a product of globalised trade and financial transactions. The work of the Iran-<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s Claims Tribunal in applying general principles such as force majeure is<br />

also said to have contributed considerably. 39 Some critics raise both theoretical and<br />

practical objections to the use of the lex mecatoria as a choice of law for international<br />

contracts. 0 There is no need to enter that debate since the empirical evidence<br />

suggests that parties do not specifically apply the general principles of the lex<br />

mercatoria as the proper law in their arbitration agreements or, if so, do it to<br />

supplement rather than displace national law. 4 Thus, only one to two percent of<br />

clauses giving rise to ICC arbitration between 2000-2003 provided for transnational<br />

or other non-national law as the governing law. 42 As indicated, however,<br />

international arbitrators seem to use the principles of the new lex mercatoria<br />

increasingly in resolving difficult points arising in the course of disputes, although<br />

43<br />

there is no systematic evidence of the extent to which this occurs.<br />

At this point, a definitional issue arises: is the new lex mercatoria to be equated<br />

with the principles, rules, and standards such as those developed by Berger? At the<br />

outset, is Lord Mustill's critique, that such principles, rules, and standards may be<br />

too vague for legal analysis in the practical world of dispute resolution for the global<br />

commercial activity?' Then there are arguments that the Berger approach is both<br />

too wide and too narrow. As to the first, some would confine the term lex mercatoria<br />

to international trade practice which arises through transnational commercial usage.<br />

The issue then becomes one of identifying usage or practice which is spontaneously<br />

36. BERGER, supra note 33.<br />

37. See CENTRAL - Center for Transnational <strong>Law</strong>, available at www.central-koeln.de.<br />

38. E.g,. Ole Lando, The Lex Mercatoria in International Commercial Arbitration, 34 Int'l & Comp.<br />

L.Q.747, 747-48 (1985); see Thomas E. Carbonneau, Rendering Arbitral Awards with Reasons: The<br />

Elaboration of a Common <strong>Law</strong> of International Transactions, 23 COLUM. J. TRANSNAT'L L. 579, 614<br />

(1985); LEX MERCATORIA AND ARBITRATION: A DISCUSSION OF THE NEW LAW MERCHANT, (Thomas<br />

E. Carbonneau ed., rev. ed. 1998).<br />

39. Maurizio Brunetti, The Lex Mercatoria in Practice: The Experience of the Iran-United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

Claims Tribunal, 18 ARB. INT'L 355,359-67 (2002).<br />

40. Peter Flanagan, Demythologising the <strong>Law</strong> Merchant: The Impropriety of the Lex Mecatoria as a<br />

Choice of <strong>Law</strong>, 15 INT'L COMPANY & COMM. L. REV. 297 (2004).<br />

41. Christopher R. Drahozal, Contracting out of National <strong>Law</strong>: An Empirical Look at the New <strong>Law</strong><br />

Merchant, 80 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 523, 538-39 (2005); Klaus P. Berger et al., The CENTRAL Enquiry on<br />

the Use of Transnational <strong>Law</strong> in International Contract <strong>Law</strong> and Arbitration - Background, Procedure and<br />

Selected Results, in THE PRACTICE OF TRANSNATIONAL LAW (Klaus P. Berger ed., 2001) (a survey of<br />

practitioners' experience).<br />

42. BERGER, supra note 33.<br />

43. Id.<br />

44. Michael Mustill, The New Lex Mercatoria: The First Twenty-Five Years, LIBER AMICORUM FOR<br />

LORD WILBERFORCE 151-53 (Maarten Bos & Ian Brownlie eds., 1987); see also Bruce L. Benson, The<br />

Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial <strong>Law</strong>, 55 S. ECON. J. 644 (1989); Christopher R. Drahozal,<br />

Commercial Norms, Commercial Codes, and International Commercial Arbitration, 33 VAND. J.<br />

TRANSNAT'L L. 79, 94-110 (2000).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 604 2006-2007


2007<br />

THEORIZING TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW<br />

generated in global commercial transactions. The doyen of academic commercial<br />

lawyers in England, Professor Sir Roy Goode, argues that the main focus of inquiry<br />

should not be the Berger-type principles, but rather the practices surrounding typical<br />

international commercial transactions. 5<br />

Though it is common to treat the lex mercatoria as including general<br />

principles of law, and I myself used to follow this approach, it seems to me<br />

on further reflection that these principles - for example pacta sunt<br />

servanda, the nemo dat rule and the duty to mitigate loss suffered from a<br />

breach of contract - are not particular to international trade or even to<br />

commercial contracts, are qualified by numerous exceptions and tell us<br />

nothing about the process of spontaneous lawmaking which is said to be<br />

the hallmark of the lex mercatoria. If we look at the lists of rules of the lex<br />

mercatoria propounded by modern scholars and remove from it general<br />

principles of law, we find that almost nothing is left, while on the other<br />

hand there is a conspicuous absence of references to important modern<br />

usages in relation to documentary credits, demand guarantees, and<br />

clearing and settlement systems for the transfer of funds and investment<br />

securities. 46<br />

Either way-the Berger principles or the Goode trade usage-the lex<br />

mercatoria is only a small aspect of the new transnational commercial law, which<br />

extends to the uniform principles, model laws, and international conventions already<br />

outlined. These are neither confined to custom and practice in global transactions<br />

nor the type of principles incorporated in the UNIDROIT Principles of International<br />

Commercial Contracts.<br />

Putting aside these definitional issues and taking a broad view of the new<br />

transnational commercial law, how is all this activity explained in theoretical terms?<br />

As far as the lex mercatoria is concerned, its advocates have as a prime contention<br />

that it is autonomous and transnational. Not only is it free from the conflicting<br />

principles of national law, but as a corollary, through the complexities of private<br />

international law, it avoids the problems of choosing between those principles.<br />

Berger argues that it has grown up in this way because of the trend towards a "global<br />

civil society," in which there is an erosion of national boundaries in markets and a<br />

relative decline of state power to steer national or international economic factors. 47<br />

The upshot is the growth of party autonomy and the privatisation of international<br />

commercial law-making, notably through arbitration. So the modern lex mercatoria,<br />

in this view, is a spillover of the complex institutional processes connected with the<br />

phenomenon of globalisation. 8 The codification of the lex mecatoria, as<br />

incorporated into uniform principles such as the UNIDROIT commercial contract<br />

45. Roy Goode, Usage and its Reception in Transnational Commercial <strong>Law</strong>, 46 INT'L & COMP. L.Q.<br />

1(1997).<br />

46. Roy Goode, Rule, Practice and Pragmatism in Transnational Commercial <strong>Law</strong>, 54 INT'L & COMP.<br />

L.Q. 539, 548 (2005); See also Goode, supra note 45, at 32-33.<br />

47. Klaus P. Berger, The New <strong>Law</strong> Merchant and the Global Market: A 21' Century View of<br />

Transnational Commercial <strong>Law</strong>, 3 INT. ARB. L. REV. 91 (2000).<br />

48. Id. at 100; see also Gunther Teubner, 'Global Bukowina': Legal Pluralism in the World Society, in<br />

GLOBAL LAW WITHOUT A STATE 40 (Gunther Teubner ed.. 1997).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 605 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:597<br />

principles, can therefore be regarded as responding to the demand believed to exist<br />

amongst the business community working in this globalised environment.<br />

Apart from the lex mercatoria, there is the wider field of transnational<br />

commercial law promulgated under the auspices of bodies such as UNCITRAL,<br />

UNIDROIT, and the ICC. Here, harmonisation has been a typical goal, with the<br />

rules of different legal systems being replaced by a uniform law, which can either be<br />

incorporated in international contracts or adopted by national legal systems (either<br />

through adoption of a model law or adherence to an international convention). In<br />

recent times, the aim has been not only harmonization, but also to improve rules in<br />

situations where the national legal rules are non-existent, underdeveloped, or<br />

unsuitable to international transactions. 49 A good illustration of the latter is the<br />

Cape Town Convention on International Interests in Mobile Equipment, which is<br />

designed to overcome the problems of financiers obtaining a secured interest over<br />

what could be categorized as global assets-aircraft, railway rolling stock, and space<br />

assets that by their nature regularly move across national borders. The Convention<br />

and its attendant protocols create an international interest, recognised in all<br />

contracting states and registerable in a public international register, which neatly<br />

side-steps the diversity of national laws on secured transactions and confers on<br />

financiers an enforceable priority in the event of the debtor's insolvency: °<br />

Outsiders to the process of formulating the new transnational commercial law<br />

have sometimes had a more jaded view of its application and development. For<br />

example, Dezalay and Garth see the lex mecatoria not so much as a response to<br />

globalisation but in terms of the rent-seeking, material interests of international<br />

arbitrators and their clients." In their analysis of the evolution of modern<br />

international commercial arbitration, they identified two main areas of tension.<br />

First, there was a struggle between those offering arbitration services - on the one<br />

hand was an older cadre of mainly continental academics, adherents of the lex<br />

mercatoria, and on the other, increasingly, Anglo-American legal practitioners,<br />

adherents to the doctrines and techniques of the common law. Secondly, there was a<br />

north-south tension: foreign investors did not want resort to local courts and law if<br />

disputes arose over construction and other projects but had to accommodate the<br />

objection of developing countries to the use of western law and courts. International<br />

arbitration using the lex mercatoria became the way through for both the European<br />

pioneers of international arbitration and for foreign investors. So the lex mecatoria<br />

not only permitted foreign investors to win time when confronted with the escalation<br />

of demands of developing countries, but also allowed its investors to preserve their<br />

position for a period vis-A-vis the challenge provided by Anglo-American law firms."<br />

49. Roy Goode, Rule, Practice and Pragmatism in Transnational Commercial <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 46, at<br />

556; see Jeffrey Wool, Rethinking the Notion of Uniformity in the Drafting of International Commercial<br />

<strong>Law</strong>: A Preliminary Proposal for the Development of a Policy-based Unification Model, 2 UNIFORM L.<br />

REV. 46, 46-47 (1997); Kazuaki Sono, The Rise of Anational Contract <strong>Law</strong> in the Age of Globalisation, 75<br />

TUL. L. REV. 1185, 1191-92 (2001).<br />

50. Roy Goode, The Cape Town Convention on International Interests in Mobile Equipment: a<br />

Driving Force for International Asset-Based Finance, 7 UNIFORM L. REV. 3, 4 (2002); Roy Goode, Official<br />

Commentary on the Convention on International Interests in Mobile Equipment and the Protocol thereto, on<br />

Matters Specific to Aircraft Equipment (2002).<br />

51. YVES DEZALAY & BRYANT G. GARTH, DEALING IN VIRTUE: INTERNATIONAL COMMERCIAL<br />

ARBITRATION AND THE CONSTRUCTION OF A TRANSNATIONAL LEGAL ORDER 41 (1996)<br />

52. Id. at 89; see also LEX MERCATORIA AND ARBITRATION, supra note 38.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 606 2006-2007


2007<br />

THEORIZING TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW<br />

In this account the time of the lex mercatoria is coming to an end as the "European<br />

pioneers" are being replaced by the Anglo-American law firms. 3<br />

Similarly, the forces behind the cluster of international conventions, model<br />

rules, and principles can be seen in a more materialistic light. Thus, the "political<br />

economy" of the Cape Town Convention on International Interests in Mobile<br />

Equipment includes the privatisation of many national airlines, and some railways,<br />

with finance increasingly from private rather than state sources and the consequent<br />

demand by global financial institutions for recognition and protection of their<br />

secured interests in such high value assets. It is said that in the process leading to the<br />

Convention, interest groups representing industry, especially the aviation industry,<br />

were particluarly active." In this account, their involvement led to "bright line" rules<br />

in the Aircraft Protocol protective of secured interests. The danger is said to be a<br />

perception that the rules fit the preferences of the more powerful nations likely to be<br />

host to the banks providing secured finance."<br />

While there is an element of truth in this type of analysis, it certainly does not<br />

stand up in its entirety. In relation to the lex mercatoria, there is a plausibility to the<br />

argument that those practicing as international commercial arbitrators need to<br />

attract work. Whether expertise in the lex mercatoria was ever the way of doing this<br />

is open to argument unless it is seen as just one part of the arbitrator's reputation.<br />

Moreover, any argument that the lex mercatoria was used as the way of meeting<br />

developing-country demands does not fit some important facts, such as the regular<br />

appearance of English and New York law as the governing law of investment and<br />

finance contracts involving those countries. As to the forces behind international<br />

conventions, model laws, and statements of principle, there is certainly a case for<br />

closer inquiry of the process in this important area of law-making. This paper is one<br />

attempt at doing that. But if, say, the aviation industry had a heavy input into the<br />

Aviation Protocol of the Cape Town Convention, that should not be a surprise nor<br />

necessarily a cause for condemnation. If a commercial instrument is to meet its<br />

professed aim, then those most affected by its operation need to be part of the<br />

process of formulating it. What is necessary is that the process must be transparent<br />

and must accord all interests an opportunity to have an influence. With international<br />

commercial lawmaking, the input of developing counties is especially important, not<br />

least if an instrument is to have legitimacy and be widely adopted.<br />

II.<br />

THE RULE OF LAW AND ITS CONSEQUENCES<br />

That the rule of law has prominence in the so-called Washington consensus is in<br />

part a response to the changes associated with the process of economic globalisation,<br />

6<br />

the spread of democracy, and the enhanced authority of international human rights.<br />

In recent decades, a conventional wisdom has also evolved linking the rule of law<br />

53. DEZALAY & BRYANT, supra note 51, at 89.<br />

54. Iwan Davies, The New Lex Mercatoria: International Interests in Mobile Equipment, 52 INT'L &<br />

COMP. L.Q. 151, 162 (2003).<br />

55. Id. at 175.<br />

56. Julio Faundez, The Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Enterprise: Promoting a Dialogue Between Practitioners and<br />

Academics, 12 DEMOCRATIZATION 567,568 (2005).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 607 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:597<br />

with economic growth, sustainable development, and poverty alleviation. 7<br />

Multilateral financial institutions like the World Bank, regional development banks<br />

like the Asian Development Bank, and some industry organisations and NGOs<br />

advocate for national principles of good governance, including a legal system of a<br />

type associated with the rule of law." It is said that law can have an impact on<br />

development by facilitating economic activity through encouraging savings and<br />

assisting in the allocation of capital." It can do this by having predictably<br />

transparent and enforceable rules for the economy, which ensure well-functioning<br />

and regulated markets, appropriate business forms with high standards of corporate<br />

governance, and efficient methods for dealing with default and insolvency in markets<br />

and businesses.6 Government subject to law is part of the equation, to guarantee<br />

that insiders cannot use state power to trump arbitrarily property and contractual<br />

rights recognised by law. 6<br />

In modern accounts, the rule of law has both procedural and substantive<br />

aspects-a legal system with an independent, impartial, and non-corrupt judiciary;<br />

laws that are clear, publicly available, and in accordance with the constitution and<br />

human rights; and an accessible, efficient court system which protects contractual,<br />

property, and human rights and provides for judicial review of government action. 62<br />

Some like Professor Armartya Sen would contend that rule of law reform along<br />

these lines must be valued in itself as part of the development process, not just for<br />

the way it may aid economic or any other type of development. 63 Another line of<br />

argument is that rule of law reforms by themselves are only part of the story. For<br />

development to occur, what is also needed is legal empowerment of the<br />

disadvantaged, which will benefit them in a broad array of fields that may not have a<br />

strict legal dimension, such as education, public health promotion, and agriculture.'<br />

Both glosses on the basic argument have great force.<br />

Even if all this is accepted, there is still the difficulty of identifying what follows<br />

from rule of law analysis in relation to specific laws, particularly commercial laws.<br />

Many of the early advocates of rule of law for promoting economic development<br />

were economists, so it is not surprising that their concern with legal detail was<br />

minimal. Early on, their focus was technical assistance for reform of the<br />

infrastructure and administration of courts and judicial training. Suffice to say that,<br />

in relation to commercial law, what has happened is that the new transnational<br />

commercial law has generally been accepted as containing the prescriptions<br />

necessary for domestic reform consistent with the rule of law model. This should not<br />

57. There is a growing body of literature about economic growth that is "pro-poor." See Martin<br />

Ravallion, Pro-Poor Growth: A Primer (World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3242, 2004).<br />

58. E.g., Ibrahim F. I. Shihata, Democracy and Development, 46 INT'L & COMP. L.Q. 635 (1997);<br />

Thomas Carothers, The Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Revival, 77 FOREIGN AFF. 95 (1998); Promoting the Rule of <strong>Law</strong><br />

Abroad, (Carnegie Endowment, Democracy and Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Project, Working Paper No. 34, 2003).<br />

59. Richard A. Posner, Creating a Legal Framework for Economic Development, 13 WORLD BANK<br />

RESEARCH OBSERVER 1 (1998).<br />

60. Id. at 1 (1998).<br />

61. Id.<br />

62. E.g., Paul P. Craig, Formal and Substantive Conceptions of the Rule of <strong>Law</strong>, 1997 PUB. LAW 467<br />

(1997); T.R.S. ALLAN, CONSTITUTIONAL JUSTICE (2001); William Whitford, The Rule of <strong>Law</strong>, 2000 WIS.<br />

L. REV. 723 (2000).<br />

63. AMARTYA SEN, DEVELOPMENT AS FREEDOM 37 (1999).<br />

64. Legal Empowerment: Advancing Good Governance and Poverty Reduction 8 (Asian Development<br />

Bank RETA 5856, 2001).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 608 2006-2007


2007<br />

THEORIZING TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW<br />

be surprising when important components of the new transnational commercial law<br />

have been generated under the auspices of rule of law advocates like the World<br />

Bank. Whatever the defects of some of the analysis, the rule of law matters. That<br />

means that along with a transparent and democratic political system, efficient<br />

bureaucracy, and developed public institutions, reforms in the commercial sector<br />

which will encourage investment, reduce corruption and cronyism, and generally<br />

contribute to social and economic development." So what is the evidence that law<br />

matters-that the effort to give legislative force to the prescriptions of the new<br />

transnational commercial law is worthwhile?<br />

There is some historical evidence of a link between the rule of law and<br />

economic development.' Over the last decade, there have also been a number of<br />

large, cross-country studies which, by using proxies for rule of law measures such as<br />

the quality of legal institutions, lend support to the thesis. 67 Yet it is no use<br />

pretending that the relationship between rule of law reform and economic<br />

development is simple; as always, real world contingency must be taken into account.<br />

It may be that, in some respects, it is economic development which facilitates a<br />

better-functioning legal system or that factors such as investment or political change<br />

move both economic development and legal reform in the same direction.' Another<br />

difficulty with the rule of law-economic development causation is identifying the<br />

relevant factors in the relationship. Is the key to economic growth the symbolic<br />

value of new law on the books, or is the effectiveness in practice of legal institutions,<br />

such as commercial law as practiced and market and financial regulation, more<br />

significant? Is governmental accountability, not least through the courts, a necessary<br />

element of the rule of law, and if so, how do we explain the East Asian model of<br />

economic development (best exemplified these days by China)? 6 There is also the<br />

puzzle of foreign investors, who are important in bridging the gap between<br />

investment and savings. While they may say that they desire a legal system with a<br />

clear framework for contracting, one which both protects property-including<br />

intellectual property rights-and provides for the timely resolution of disputes; in<br />

practice, the existence of business opportunities means that they may invest heavily<br />

in countries where these basic features of the rule of law are absent."<br />

65. On the earlier law and development movement, see David Trubek & Mark Galanter, Scholars in<br />

Self-Estrangement: Some Reflections on the Crisis in <strong>Law</strong> and Development, 1974 Wis. L. REV. 1062 (1974);<br />

Brian Z. Tamanaha, Review Article: The Lessons of <strong>Law</strong>-and-Development Studies, 89 AM. J. INT'L. L. 470<br />

(1995): Julio Faundez, Legal Technical Assistance, in GOOD GOVERNMENT AND LAW, 1 (Julio Faundez<br />

ed., 1997).<br />

66. E.g., P.S. ATIYAH, THE RISE AND FALL OF FREEDOM OF CONTRACT (1979); DOUGLAS NORTH,<br />

INSTITUTIONS, INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE (1990); KATHARINA PISTOR &<br />

PHILIP A. WELLONS, THE ROLE OF LAW AND LEGAL INSTITUTIONS IN ASIAN ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT<br />

1960-1995 (1999).<br />

67. See Rafael La Porta et al., Legal Determinants of External Finance, 52 J. FIN. 1131 (1997); Rafael<br />

La Porta et al., <strong>Law</strong> and Finance, 106 J. POL. ECON. 1113 (1998).<br />

68. Richard E. Messick, Judicial Reform and Economic Development: A Survey of the Issues. 14<br />

World Bank Resource Observer 117,122 (1999).<br />

69. See Frank K. Upham, Mythmaking in the Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Orthodoxy, (Carnegie Endowment for<br />

International Peace, Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Series, Working Paper No. 30, 2002); Carol A. G. Jones, Capitalism,<br />

Globalization, Rule of <strong>Law</strong>, 3 SOC. & LEGAL STUDIES 195 (1994).<br />

70. Amanda Perry-Kessaris, Finding and Facing Facts About Legal Systems and Foreign Direct<br />

Investment in South Asia, 2003 LEGAL STUDIES 649, 651-52 (2003).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 609 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:597<br />

Moreover, the law's contribution to development in practice is a long-term and<br />

tortuous process. As a matter of public policy, it demands a sensitivity to its inherent<br />

limits, the context in which it operates, and the force of other social and economic<br />

factors. 7 ' There is always the potential for unintended consequences. A helpful<br />

illustration pertinent to the issue of credit and security law is provided by the<br />

colonial courts in India, which were superimposed on a system where informal<br />

sanctions operated in rural areas to guarantee the repayment of credit, but which<br />

also encouraged money-lenders to carry debtors in difficult times. In one account,<br />

new creditors, with access to the enforcement mechanisms of the colonial courts,<br />

entered the market and forced down margins, which in turn reduced the capacity of<br />

local money-lenders to accommodate debtors in difficulty. 7 The same unintended<br />

consequences are bound to occur in certain contexts on the domestic adoption of the<br />

new transnational commercial law.<br />

How the law actually operates is at least as important as the law in the books.<br />

Using law such as commercial and financial law for utilitarian ends means<br />

acknowledging, for example, the importance of non-state norms such as commercial<br />

custom, informal methods of social control, and alternative mechanisms of dispute<br />

resolution. Also, it should not be forgotten that the law's outcomes are not valuefree<br />

and that the law can be part of the struggle for power in society. Protecting<br />

contractual and property rights may simply shield what a powerful, and possibly<br />

corrupt, elite have seized under the cover of state power. Even more benign<br />

societies recognize the need for legislative controls and well-oiled regulatory<br />

agencies to curb the abuses associated with free contracting and markets. Apart<br />

from equity concerns, the state must police markets to curb corrupt and predatory<br />

practices which undermine their very integrity. Additionally, creating a system<br />

which works for private economic interests does not mean overlooking values such<br />

as equality before the law, the wider public interest, and protecting the more<br />

vulnerable in society.<br />

III. THE POWER OF THE MARKET<br />

Financial markets respond favourably to whether a society controls public debt<br />

and inflation, restricts state control of enterprises, and facilitates rather than hinders<br />

foreign trade. Legal categorisation of a society can also affect market perceptions.<br />

Consider the rather simplistic characterisation of legal systems along a spectrum<br />

from pro-creditor to pro-debtor. 3 The more pro-creditor a society, the more<br />

favourable the market perceptions become, which can lead internationally to greater<br />

foreign investment and economic activity. The nature of a country's commercial and<br />

financial laws is an important factor affecting where a country falls along the<br />

spectrum. Adoption of many of the prescriptions of the new transnational<br />

commercial law, despite the regulatory bent of some of it, would generally move a<br />

country along the spectrum in the pro-creditor direction. The World Bank's<br />

guidelines on insolvency and creditor rights are a good illustration. Take, as an<br />

71. Patrick McAuslan, Path Dependency, <strong>Law</strong> and Development, 1 J. COMMONWEALTH L.& LEGAL<br />

ED. 51,58 (2001).<br />

72. Rachel E. Kranton & Anand V. Swamy, The Hazards of Piecemeal Reform: British Civil Courts<br />

and the Credit Market in Colonial India, 58 J. DEV. ECON. 1, 12-15 (1999).<br />

73. See Rafael La Porta et al., Legal Determinants of External Finance, supra note 80; Rafael La Porta<br />

et al., <strong>Law</strong> and Finance, supra note 80.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 610 2006-2007


2007<br />

THEORIZING TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW<br />

aspect, the provision of credit, in particular the role of security (collateral) in<br />

facilitating this. Broadly, secured transactions law gives creditors and investors a<br />

priority claim against the debtor's property (the collateral) should the debtor be<br />

unable or unwilling to pay in accordance with the credit or investment contract. The<br />

nature of an effective security law for an economy is advanced in the World Bank<br />

Guidelines in this way:<br />

The legal framework should provide for the creation, recognition, and<br />

enforcement of security interests in movable and immovable (real) property, arising<br />

by agreement or operation of law. The law should provide for the following<br />

features:<br />

Security interests in all types of assets, movable and immovable, tangible<br />

and intangible, including inventory, receivables, and proceeds; future or<br />

after-acquired property, and on a global basis; and based on both<br />

possessory and non-possessory interests;<br />

Methods of notice that will sufficiently publicize the existence of security<br />

interests to creditors, purchasers, and the public generally at the lowest<br />

possible cost;<br />

Clear rules of priority governing competing claims or interests in the same<br />

assets...<br />

Enforcement procedures should provide for prompt realization of the<br />

rights obtained in secured assets, ensuring the maximum possible recovery<br />

of asset values based on market values. Both nonjudicial and judicial<br />

enforcement methods should be considered. 74<br />

As we see below, the force of the guidelines is enhanced by their use by the<br />

IMF and World Bank as international best practice in financial sector assessments of<br />

individual countries. A recent study of the Asian Development Bank underlines the<br />

importance of small- and medium-sized enterprises to sustainable economic growth. 75<br />

It argues that the key to their success is access to readily available, cheap, long-term<br />

74. World Bank, Principles and Guidelines for Effective Insolvency and Credit Rights Regimes, excerpt<br />

in [2003] World Bank Leg R627, Principles 3 & 5; see also U.N. Comm. on Int'l Trade <strong>Law</strong>, Working<br />

Group 6 Security Interests. Draft Legislative Guide on Secured Transactions A/CN.9/WG.VI/WP.24/Add. 2<br />

(Nov. 24, 2005); Spyridon V. Bazinas, UNCITRAL's Work in the Field of Secured Transactions, in<br />

EMERGING FINANCIAL MARKETS AND SECURED TRANSACTIONS (Joseph Norton & Mads Andenas eds.,<br />

1998).<br />

75. Ross Cranston. Credit Security and Debt Recovery: <strong>Law</strong>'s Role in Reform in Asia and the Pacific,<br />

in EMERGING FINANCIAL MARKETS AND SECURED TRANSACTIONS (Joseph Norton and Mads Andenas<br />

eds., 1998).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 611 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:597<br />

credit that turns on a legal framework enabling small borrowers to give security over<br />

their movable property; unlike larger enterprises, they are less likely to be able to<br />

offer land and buildings as security. 76 That security must be readily enforceable on<br />

default.<br />

Enhancing creditors' rights in this way has considerable intuitive appeal. That<br />

security rights under credit and investment agreements are readily enforceable,<br />

possibly without resort to the court, means that lenders and investors can more<br />

accurately manage and control the risk of default. It encourages discipline on the<br />

part of debtors. Disputes are more readily resolvable in the shadow of the law. By<br />

contrast, if enforcement of a credit or investment contract is doubtful, creditors and<br />

investors cannot price the risk of default accurately. A premium needs to be<br />

extracted to compensate for the uncertainty or for the risk of non-performance. In<br />

some cases, the confidence of creditors and investors may be so eroded that credit is<br />

altogether unavailable."<br />

Perhaps the best example in the legal literature of a categorisation of legal<br />

systems in a manner relevant to market perceptions has been advanced by Philip<br />

Wood. Beginning in 1995, Wood developed a comprehensive and sophisticated<br />

analysis that eschews a simplistic pro-creditor/pro-debtor division and instead<br />

divides the financial law world according to five key criteria: 1) the availability of<br />

insolvency set-off; 2) the marketability of contracts, receivables, and claims; 3) the<br />

availability and scope of security interests; 4) the availability of the commercial trust;<br />

and 5) whether tracing delinquent money is possible. 8 Wood concedes that his<br />

mapping is not exact, is in some respects incomplete, and relies to an extent on<br />

subjective judgment. 79 Nonetheless, he says that the differences between<br />

jurisdictions are striking. ° The criteria are tested mainly on insolvency and go to the<br />

efficiency of the financial system, the extent to which risks are reduced, and whether<br />

the legal system facilitates economic development. 8 ' Wood concludes,<br />

controversially, that the traditional Napoleonic systems are negative on all of these,<br />

the Roman-Germanic systems are negative on just over half of them and positive on<br />

the other half, and the Anglo-American systems are positive on all five. 82 While he<br />

concedes substantial similarities across large areas of law, on these five aspects of<br />

commercial law, there still remain significant differences. 3<br />

Not surprisingly, given the huge task which would be involved, Wood's<br />

taxonomy does not include the impact of the rules, their actual implementation, or<br />

compliance with them in practice. 8 ' Of course, laws in themselves have symbolic<br />

significance. Yet in any society, law works against a background of social factors.<br />

Unless this context is taken into account, the workings of the law will not be properly<br />

understood, and efforts at reform will be misguided. One aspect is that a problem<br />

might not lie in inadequate laws or legal procedures but in the way law is enforced or<br />

76. Id.<br />

77. Barry Adler, Secured Credit Contracts, in 3 NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND<br />

THE LAW 405 (Peter K. Newman ed., 1998).<br />

78. PHILIP R. WOOD, PRINCIPLES OF INTERNATIONAL INSOLVENCY 10-12 (1995).<br />

79. Id.<br />

80. Id.<br />

81. Id.<br />

82. Id.<br />

83. See id. at 59.<br />

84. See generally WOOD, supra note 78, at 13.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 612 2006-2007


2007<br />

THEORIZING TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW<br />

operates in a society. Thus, it is well known that in Japan, litigation is relatively rare,<br />

and parties seek to avoid court." 5 This could mean that it is more likely that when,<br />

say, a borrower is having difficulty repaying, a Japanese bank may not invoke the<br />

very wide powers conferred on it by the loan agreement. Rather, the borrower<br />

might receive visits from the bank and find its freedom of action curtailed as the<br />

bank prescribes a remedial course. Whether this has also resulted in Japanese banks<br />

implicitly promising to rescue troubled but viable firms-the conventional wisdom<br />

86<br />

now under fierce challenge-is beyond the scope of the present inquiry.<br />

Regarding law reform, what will be needed is a careful and painstaking<br />

identification of the problems in a particular jurisdiction and the possible legal<br />

solutions. There will be no easy answers. Sensitivity to the context of the law is<br />

essential. A blanket introduction of "pro-creditor" laws without taking this into<br />

account could result in yet more ineffective laws. Indeed, it could well be<br />

counterproductive: schemes, both simple and sophisticated, will be devised to avoid<br />

their impact, and in extreme cases courts will simply refuse to apply what they see as<br />

draconian laws in their impact on debtors, further undermining the rule of law. And<br />

there will also be social justice issues if adequate protections are not incorporated<br />

into creditor laws, notably in favour of consumer debtors.<br />

There can be little doubt that perceptions of whether a country is pro-creditor<br />

or pro-debtor, or where they fall along the spectrum in more sophisticated analyses<br />

like Wood's feed into decisions by international markets, especially foreign investors<br />

and lenders. Rating agencies, so important in channelling international capital, are<br />

one influence and have some version of a pro-creditor or pro-debtor model as part<br />

of their assessment processes. This is reinforced by FSAP and ROSC assessments of<br />

countries by the IMF and World Bank. 7 The Financial Sector Assessment Program<br />

(FSAP) involves the IMF and World Bank working together to prevent financial<br />

instability in one country threatening others. To do this, a system of benchmarks is<br />

used as an early warning mechanism-at an international level, as minimum<br />

standards for transparency, market efficiency, and financial discipline-and at a<br />

national level to guide policy reform. Countries are then evaluated against the<br />

benchmarks in Reports on the Observance of Standards and Codes (ROSCs);<br />

among the benchmarks are some of the key parts of the new transnational<br />

commercial law. 8<br />

From the academic point of view, pro-creditor/pro-debtor mapping is a useful<br />

heuristic device in considering the issues that any national system of commercial law<br />

must address. Recall that in practice it will be difficult to place a country accurately;<br />

recall also that the purpose of the exercise is not to make moral judgments, but to<br />

isolate problems and then to suggest possible legal reforms; recall that a legal<br />

85. E.g., CARL F. GOODMAN, THE RULE OF LAW IN JAPAN (2003), 230-32; Yukiko Hasebe, Civil<br />

Justice Reform: Access, Cost and Expedition. The Japanese Perspective, in CIVIL JUSTICE IN CRISIS 248<br />

(Adrian Zuckerman ed. 1999).<br />

86. E.g., Yoshiro Miwa & J. Mark Ramseyer, The Myth of the Main Bank: Japan and Comparative<br />

Corporate Governance, 27 L. & SOC. INQUIRY 401 (2002).<br />

87. Duncan E. Alford, Core Principles for Effective Banking Supervision: An Enforceable<br />

International Financial Standard? 28 B.C. INT'L & COMP. L. REV. 237, 273-74 (2005) (extensive information<br />

about the International Monetary Fund's Financial Assessment Programme); see The World Bank Group,<br />

Reports on the Observance of Standards & Codes (ROSC), available at www.worldbank.org/ifa/rosc.html<br />

(details of the "Report on Observance of Standards and Codes").<br />

88. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 613 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:597<br />

system's economic effectiveness may actually decline if it becomes too "procreditor";<br />

and recall, finally, that social justice issues cannot be ignored. Despite<br />

these qualifications, issues such as the free transfer of contracts and receivables are<br />

crucial if the law is to respond flexibly to new methods of financing and doing<br />

business. This is equally true with respect to important parts of the package of<br />

measures falling under the rubric of the new transnational commercial law.<br />

IV.<br />

IMPLEMENTING THE NEW TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW<br />

Some aspects of the new transnational commercial law need to be adopted by<br />

private parties if they are to be effective. For decades banks have incorporated the<br />

Uniform Customs and Practice for Documentary Credits, issued by the International<br />

Chamber of Commerce, into their standard documentation for letters of credit.<br />

Similarly, UNIDROIT's Principles of International Commercial Contracts will need<br />

to be referred to in international contracts as the proper law if they are to be<br />

invoked on a regular basis in international commercial arbitration. Otherwise,<br />

although an international arbitrator may still refer to the Principles as guidelines, he<br />

will have a difficult task of overtaking national systems of law as the key factors in an<br />

arbitrator's decision making. 9 Before the bulk of the new transnational commercial<br />

law can take effect, however, it needs to be adopted legislatively in domestic<br />

jurisdictions. For example, private parties have only limited scope to choose the<br />

insolvency or regulatory law to govern their transactions.<br />

What has been said already militates against a notion that economic<br />

development follows from a blind legislative adoption into domestic law of the<br />

standards, codes, and principles of the new transnational commercial law. It cannot<br />

be assumed that their introduction will automatically occasion economic stability,<br />

facilitate sophisticated economic transactions, foster the establishment of complex<br />

enterprises, or further the resolution of legal disputes. This is quite apart from the<br />

adverse reaction which could follow as a result of transplantation of these models<br />

being interpreted as a form of neo-colonial domination. Ideally, an incremental<br />

approach is desirable, drawing on theory and international best practice, and over<br />

time melding the prescriptions of the new transnational commercial law to local<br />

conditions in the light of accumulated experience. 9 " In many cases, copying foreign<br />

models is unavoidable because of the pressure of time, the lack of expertise, and the<br />

demands of outside interests for immediate action. 91 It might also be that a window<br />

of opportunity for fundamental law reform presents itself; the ideal in these<br />

circumstances is a counsel of perfection and will thus miss this window of<br />

opportunity.<br />

At the level of theory, Montesquieu argued that it was unlikely that the laws of<br />

one nation would suit another, given the variety of environmental factors making up<br />

89. Anthony S. Winer, The CISG Convention and Thomas Franck's Theory of Legitimacy, 19 Nw. J.<br />

INT'L L. & Bus. 55, 55-56 (1998); see also THOMAS M. FRANCK, THE POWER OF LEGITIMACY AMONG<br />

NATIONS (2002).<br />

90. See generally Ann Seidman & Robert B. Seidman, Using Reason and Experience to Draft Country-<br />

Specific <strong>Law</strong>s, in MAKING DEVELOPMENT WORK (Ann Seidman et al. eds., 1999).<br />

91. Thomas W. Walde & James L. Gunderson, Legislative Reform in Transition Economies: Western<br />

Transplants: A Short-cut to Social Market Economy Status?, in MAKING DEVELOPMENT WORK, 92-95<br />

(Ann Seidman et al. eds., 1999).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 614 2006-2007


2007<br />

THEORIZING TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW<br />

"the spirit of the law." 92 In a more modern account, Professor Otto Kahn-Freund<br />

thought it possible to transplant law, but emphasised the very great difficulties. 93<br />

Factors, which in his account are especially important, are political institutions,<br />

ideologies, and the power structure. 4 Professor Alan Watson's contrary thesis is that<br />

transplants can readily be made. 95 The law has a strong autonomy from societal<br />

forces, such as the culture of the legal elite-legislators, jurists, or judges-who have<br />

control of the accepted mechanisms of legal change. Watson accepts that although<br />

legal institutions will not exist without corresponding social institutions, law evolves<br />

from the legal tradition rather than the social context. 9 6 Lending support to<br />

Watson's view are Roman law and other major episodes of legal transplantation:<br />

Napoleon carried his code to other parts of Europe; in the nineteenth and first part<br />

of the twentieth century, imperial powers, like Britain, took their laws to other parts<br />

of the world, like India; and in recent decades, as we have seen, international<br />

financial institutions like the World Bank have successfully marketed their models to<br />

developing and emerging economies.<br />

So at a purely formal level, law can be transplanted. The obvious issue is: does<br />

a transplanted law become living law, and if so, how? There are no easy answers.<br />

Taxonomies in which certain families of law transplant efficiently and other<br />

ineffectively are not especially convincing. 97 Nor are some of the massive empirical<br />

studies that give them some support. What can be said is that a transplanted law is<br />

changed in use: it will be transformed through interpretation and application, and<br />

amended formally to take in local conditions. Secondly, whatever the law,<br />

commercial activity goes on. Thus, in England and the United <strong>State</strong>s, informal<br />

norms, as with commercial customs, have always been part of the working of the law.<br />

In some situations, transplanted law may have a greater chance in some areas, in<br />

particular the investment and financial sectors, because receptivity and demand are<br />

present, especially among foreign investors. 8 But commercial laws which trench on<br />

rights in the wider community may be more likely to be resisted. The examples of<br />

security and insolvency law fall into this category if they threaten employees'<br />

continued employment in a jurisdiction which has comparatively little in the way of a<br />

social security system. Nonetheless, criminal and family laws have been successfully<br />

transplanted, even those laws which were initially forced onto a jurisdiction. 99 Such<br />

transplants may have had a catalytic effect. It seems that the positive attitude of<br />

92. J.W.F. ALLISON, A CONTINENTAL DISTINCTION IN THE COMMON LAW 12-13 (1996).<br />

93. Otto Kahn-Freund, On Uses and Misuses of Comparative <strong>Law</strong>, 37 MOD. L.REV. 1, 7-10 (1974).<br />

94. Id.; see also Andrew Rosser, The Political Economy of Institutional Reform in Indonesia, in LAW,<br />

CAPITALISM AND POWER IN ASIA: THE RULE OF LAW AND LEGAL INSTITUTIONS (Kanishka Jayasuriya<br />

ed., 1999).<br />

95. ALAN WATSON, THE EVOLUTION OF LAW 119 (1985).<br />

96. Id.; see also ALAN WATSON, SOCIETY AND LEGAL CHANGE 98-111 (2d ed. 2001).<br />

97. See generally Daniel Berkowitz et al., Economic Development, Legality and the Transplant Effect,<br />

47 EUR. ECON. REV. 165 (2003); see also Ugo Mattei, Efficiency in Legal Transplants: An Essay in<br />

Comparative <strong>Law</strong> and Economics, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 3 (1994); Ugo Mattei, Three Patterns of <strong>Law</strong>:<br />

Taxonomy and Change in the World's Legal Systems, 45 AM. J. COMP. L. 5 (1997); Malcolm D. H. Smith,<br />

Comparative <strong>Law</strong> and Legal Culture, 15 BOND L. REV. 20 (2003).<br />

98. Frederick Schauer, The Politics and Incentives of Legal Transplantation (Center for International<br />

Development at Harvard University, Working Paper No. 44, 2000).<br />

99. Andrew Harding, Global Doctrine and Local Knowledge: <strong>Law</strong> in South-East Asia, 51 INT'L &<br />

COMP. L.Q. 35. 44-45 (2002).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 615 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:597<br />

local and legal elites cannot be underestimated.lw In all, the transplant of law is a<br />

very mixed picture, but context cannot be underestimated.<br />

V. CONCLUSION<br />

My argument is that there are legal theories which help explain some aspects of<br />

the emergence and adoption of modern transnational commercial law. They cannot<br />

explain the full picture by any means. The efforts of bodies like UNCITRAL,<br />

UNIDROIT, and the World Bank have at base a concern with solving practical<br />

problems in transnational commercial law, particularly where globalisation creates<br />

gaps in the ability of national legal systems to solve them. There are many examples,<br />

but perhaps the best in recent times is the way the Cape Town Convention addresses<br />

a modern problem of how financiers and investors can take effective security over<br />

valuable, privately and state-owned mobile property such as aircraft, railway stock,<br />

and space assets like satellites. The work of the International Monetary Fund over<br />

the years in relation to central banking law-and more recently that of the Basel<br />

bodies with respect to the adequate supervision of the financial sector-the core<br />

principles for effective bank supervision and the rules for capital adequacy and<br />

sound risk management of banks can be seen broadly as motivated by a pragmatic<br />

concern with the stability of the international financial system, risk reduction, and<br />

efficiency. 1 1<br />

As we have seen, there are examples of standards from the new transnational<br />

commercial law suggested for adoption in domestic legal systems, consistent with the<br />

rule of law and pro-creditor/pro-debtor models. The World Bank, the International<br />

Monetary Fund, and regional development banks like the Asian Development Bank<br />

have all been engaged in this work. It is natural to consider carefully international<br />

commercial law having its pedigree in such a model. The forces behind the<br />

provisions consequently spun off, and their impact may be reasons for pause.<br />

Another may be the point already made that however splendid these laws may be<br />

"on the books," they may simply be an illusion of progress if there is not the<br />

administrative machinery to give them force in practice. Perhaps most important are<br />

social justice issues such as the protection of consumers and employees. If these<br />

concerns are addressed, however, it can be strongly argued that important aspects of<br />

the new transnational commercial law are as important for the poor as for others. In<br />

his book The Mystery of Capital, Professor Hernando de Soto observes that in<br />

developing countries, although the poor may have capital such as growing crops or<br />

possibly land, it is "dead" economically-it lacks adequate legal protection and,<br />

crucially, cannot be used as collateral for credit."" Access to ready finance is the<br />

preserve of the elite. Modern laws relating to credit and security are therefore<br />

needed.' 3 Whether so benign a view of the new transnational commercial law can be<br />

taken in general as opposed to this one example, depends in every case on the<br />

100. Frank B. Cross, <strong>Law</strong> and Economic Growth, 80 TEx. L. REV. 1737, 1774 (2002).<br />

101. E.g., JOSEPH J. NORTON, DEVISING INTERNATIONAL BANK SUPERVISORY STANDARDS (1995);<br />

GEORGE A. WALKER, INTERNATIONAL BANKING REGULATION: LAW, POLICY AND PRACTICE (2001);<br />

Mamiko Yoko-Arai, Financial Stability Issues: The Case of East Asia (2002).<br />

102. Id.<br />

103. HERNANDO DE SOTO, THE MYSTERY OF CAPITAL: WHY CAPITALISM TRIUMPHS IN THE WEST<br />

AND FAILS EVERYWHERE ELSE (2000).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 616 2006-2007


2007 THEORIZING TRANSNATIONAL COMMERCIAL LAW 617<br />

circumstances. Each measure must be tested not only in terms of its contribution to<br />

economic development, but also to social justice.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 617 2006-2007


HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 618 2006-2007


Developing a New Commercial Court in<br />

Ghana<br />

KOFI DATE-BAH*<br />

There has been a demand in Ghana for a Commercial Court for a long time.<br />

Indeed, while at the Commonwealth Secretariat in London, I led a team (in 1995-96)<br />

to undertake a diagnostic survey of the Ghanaian legal system with a view to<br />

identifying impediments to the development of the private sector. That team also<br />

came to the conclusion that a Commercial Court needed to be established for<br />

Ghana.'<br />

The Judiciary of Ghana responded to the growing pressure for a Commercial<br />

Court by establishing one in 2005.2 Judicial power is vested exclusively in the<br />

Judiciary under the Constitution of Ghana.' Accordingly, the Judiciary had the<br />

right, without primary legislation, to establish a Commercial Division of the High<br />

Court, the High Court being a constitutionally established superior court. The High<br />

Court in Ghana, as in England, is a court of first instance with unlimited jurisdiction. 4<br />

The current High Court is descended from a colonial High Court by which the<br />

British administration sought to replicate the English High Court in the Ghanaian<br />

jurisdiction.<br />

The establishment of the Commercial Court as a High Court was a step in the<br />

process of reforming the judicial sector. There has been such widespread<br />

dissatisfaction with the justice system in Ghana that the Government established the<br />

Legal/Judicial Sector Reform Project about a decade ago. One of the results of this<br />

Project was the establishment of an automated Fast Track Division of the High<br />

Court of Ghana to expedite the hearing of suits. To illustrate the need for this<br />

reform, it is useful to draw attention to the following passage from the Diagnostic<br />

Report of the Commonwealth Secretariat team of 1995-96:<br />

A.1. The time taken by judicial processes has been a source of complaint<br />

by business people in Ghana for a long time. The perception is not held by<br />

* Justice of the Supreme Court of Ghana.<br />

1. Economic and Legal Advisory Services Division of the Commonwealth Secretariat [ELAS],<br />

Diagnostic Survey of <strong>Law</strong>s Affecting Private Sector Development in Ghana: A Selective Analysis (on file<br />

with author) [hereinafter ELAS Report].<br />

2 Republic of Ghana Budget <strong>State</strong>ment and Economic Policy of the Government of Ghana (Feb. 21,<br />

2002) at 118-22, available at http://siteresources.worldbank.orgIGHANAEXTN/Resources/bud2002.pdf.<br />

3. CONSTITUTION OF THE REPUBLIC OF GHANA (1992), available at<br />

http://www.parliment.gh/const-constitution.php.<br />

4. Id. §130.<br />

5. See Supreme Court Ordinance 1876 of the Gold Coast Colony, reprinted in LAWS OF THE GOLD<br />

COAST (1937).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 619 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:619<br />

business people alone; it is found with persons from all walks of life who<br />

have sought the assistance of the courts in the resolution of their disputes.<br />

A.2. At the outset, it must be pointed out that the complaint is not<br />

directed at the intellectual content or correctness of judgments of the<br />

courts. No question has been raised about the basic fairness or justice of<br />

judicial decisions. The persistent complaint is over delays in the<br />

dispensation of justice. The causes of dissatisfaction are many and various:<br />

examples are the operation (and, in some cases the substance) of the<br />

procedural rules, especially the opportunities they give for obstruction and<br />

adjournment; the inability of court bailiffs, sometimes in incredible<br />

circumstances, to serve writs or other court process on parties to court<br />

actions; the manual recording of court proceedings, especially the evidence<br />

at a hearing; the number of judicial officers staffing the courts; the lack of<br />

specialised knowledge by the judges of the world of business; judicial<br />

working hours and the length of the legal term; the time judges take over<br />

the writing of their judgments; the quality and numbers of support staff;<br />

and the lack of appropriate equipment and their users for expedition of<br />

the judicial process. 6<br />

The automated Fast Track Division of the High Court of Ghana was<br />

established to enable modern information and communication technology to be<br />

applied to its processes and to relieve its judges from the drudgery of manual<br />

recording of evidence in long hand.<br />

After the Fast Track Courts had been imbedded into the judicial system, it<br />

became clear that the next step in the improvement in the justice delivery system<br />

should be the establishment of a commercial court to enhance the relevance of the<br />

judicial system to the business community. Accordingly, the Ghana Judiciary sent a<br />

delegation, sponsored by DANIDA, the Danish development agency, to Tanzania in<br />

November 2002 to observe the Tanzanian Commercial Court which had been<br />

established a few years before. 7 This mission, led by Justice Acquah, a Justice of the<br />

Supreme Court who later became the Chief Justice, was impressed by the Tanzanian<br />

precedent and, on its return, recommended the establishment of a Commercial<br />

Court in Ghana.<br />

Among the recommendations made by the mission on its return were the<br />

following:<br />

* Six High Courts should be set aside to constitute the Commercial Court<br />

of Ghana;<br />

* The Commercial Court should handle general commercial disputes<br />

involving investments, tax, and banking matters, among others;<br />

* Special rules should be enacted for the use of the Commercial Court;<br />

* Alternative Dispute Resolution processes should be integrated into the<br />

adjudication process of the Court;<br />

6. ELAS Report, supra note 1.<br />

7. Judicial Service of Ghana, Mission to Tanzania.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 620 2006-2007


2006<br />

DEVELOPING A NEW COMMERCIAL COURT IN GHANA<br />

" Judges and supporting staff should be selected immediately to undergo<br />

training; and<br />

* Information and communication technology, including the use of audio<br />

recording, should be integrated into the court's processes.'<br />

These recommendations were accepted by the Judicial Service and<br />

implemented. DANIDA provided support to the implementation process. 9 It<br />

funded a study tour by the six High Court judges selected to start the Commercial<br />

Court and their key support staff."' The tour took the selected judges to Tanzania,<br />

Uganda, Denmark, and the United Kingdom. The judges inspected the operations<br />

of the commercial courts in these countries and interacted with their judges and<br />

other staff. DANIDA also funded the construction of a modern purpose-built<br />

courthouse for the Commercial Court." The Commercial Court was formally<br />

commissioned by the President of Ghana on March 4, 2005, and is now in<br />

operation. 2<br />

The court known as the Commercial Court is technically the Commercial<br />

Division of the High Court of Ghana. Its judges are therefore High Court judges.<br />

However, the new civil procedure rules for the High Court, which came into force on<br />

January 3, 2005, enacted some special rules which are applicable only to the<br />

Commercial Court. 3<br />

Order 58 of the new rules, which contains these special rules, provides, for<br />

instance, for compulsory pre-trial settlement procedures. 4 It also authorises the use<br />

of not more than two assessors by a Commercial Court judge during a trial. At the<br />

end of the trial, the assessors may state their opinion, but their opinion is not binding<br />

on the judge. The 1995-96 team that prepared the Commonwealth Secretariat<br />

Report, invited by the Ghana Government (through the Ministry of Finance and<br />

Economic Planning), had a much broader focus than the judicial system. 5<br />

Nevertheless, the mission's report did have some observations relating to the courts.<br />

The Report recommended the use of assessors in commercial cases and<br />

recommended changes in the Rules of Court to achieve this. Clearly, this<br />

recommended reform has now been achieved with the promulgation of the new<br />

High Court (Civil Procedure) Rules, 2004 (CI 47), Order 58, rule 10, which<br />

authorises the judges of the Commercial Court to appoint not more than two<br />

assessors to assist them in any particular case. 6 The Commonwealth Secretariat<br />

recommendation went a little further than the new rule, in that it recommended that<br />

the appointment of assessors should be mandatory, where the parties request it or,<br />

even without such application, in specialised and complicated cases. It may be that<br />

8. Id.<br />

9. DANIDA, Ghana Legal and Judicial Reform Component Fact Sheet,<br />

http://www.danidadevforum.um.dk/NR/rdonlyres/679FDE29-DCFA-41CD-956C-<br />

BDDFE118CD5C/0/LegalJudicialReform FactSheet.pdf.<br />

10. Justice George Kingsley Acquah, Lord Chief Justice of the Ghanaian Supreme Court, Speech of<br />

the Lord Chief Justice on the First Anniversary of the Commercial Court, available at<br />

http://www.judicial.gov.gh/archives/com%20court/cc_3.htm.<br />

11. DANIDA, supra note 9.<br />

12. Justice George Kingsley Acquah, supra note 10.<br />

13. Ghana High Court Civil Procedure Rules, 2004 C.l. 47, Order 58.<br />

14. Id.<br />

15. See ELAS Report, supra note 1.<br />

16. Ghana High Court Civil Procedure Rules, supra note 13.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 621 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:619<br />

after an initial trial period of the system of assessors, the Judicial Service ought to<br />

consider expanding the role of assessors along the lines of the Commonwealth<br />

Secretariat recommendation. Currently, the use of assessors is entirely dependent<br />

on the discretion of the judges of the Commercial Court.<br />

Order 58 also incorporates court-based alternative dispute resolution (ADR)<br />

processes into commercial dispute resolution. 7 After the close of pleadings, the<br />

Administrator of the Commercial Court is obliged, within three days, to refer the<br />

case to one of the Commercial Court judges to conduct a pre-trial settlement<br />

conference.' 8 The pre-trial judge is, in turn, obliged to invite the parties, within thirty<br />

days, to settle the issues for trial and to endeavour to achieve a settlement of the<br />

dispute. 9 At the pre-trial settlement conference, the parties may be represented by<br />

their counsel. ° Experts may be invited by the pre-trial judge to assist the settlement<br />

process." All disclosures made or documents presented at the pre-trial conference<br />

are without prejudice. 2 Where a dispute is settled at the pre-trial settlement<br />

conference, the settlement is entered as the judgment of the court. 23<br />

The special Order 58 rules apply to commercial claims, which are defined as<br />

''any claim arising out of trade and commerce and includes any claim relating to:<br />

i. The formation or governance of a business or commercial organization.<br />

ii. The winding up or bankruptcy of a commercial or business organization or<br />

corporate person.<br />

iii. The restructuring or payment of commercial debts by or to business or<br />

commercial organization or person.<br />

iv. A business document or contract.<br />

v. The export or import of goods.<br />

vi. The carriage of goods by sea, air, land or pipeline.<br />

vii. The exploration of oil and gas reserves.<br />

viii. Insurance and re-insurance.<br />

ix. Banking and financial services.<br />

x. Business agency.<br />

xi. Disputes involving Commercial Arbitration and other settlement awards.<br />

xii. Intellectual property rights, including patents, copyrights, and trademarks.<br />

xiii. Tax matters.<br />

xiv. Commercial fraud.<br />

xv. Application under the Companies Code, 1962 (Act 179).<br />

xvi. Other claims of commercial nature." 24<br />

17. Id.<br />

18. Id.<br />

19. Id.<br />

20. Id.<br />

21. Id.<br />

22. Ghana High Court Civil Procedure Rules, supra note 13.<br />

23. Id.<br />

24. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 622 2006-2007


2006<br />

DEVELOPING A NEW COMMERCIAL COURT IN GHANA<br />

The Commercial Court's jurisdiction over these claims is not compulsory.<br />

Litigants may still go to the ordinary High Court with commercial claims if they wish.<br />

Indeed, the fees payable for the use of the Commercial Court are higher than in the<br />

ordinary courts. The belief, nevertheless, is that businessmen will pay a premium for<br />

the quicker and more focused service provided in the Commercial Court. This belief<br />

has in fact been borne out by experience. The statistics from the first year of<br />

operation of the Commercial Court show a healthy patronage by the business<br />

community and expeditious disposal of cases by the judges.<br />

An innovation, in relation to the Ghanaian jurisdiction, that has been<br />

introduced in connection with the Commercial Court is the Users Committee of the<br />

Court. The Users Committee consists of a Supreme Court Judge, representing the<br />

Chief Justice (who is the Chairman of it and who happens to be the current author);<br />

all the judges of the Commercial Court; one representative from the Attorney-<br />

General's Office; one representative of the Ghana Bar Association; one<br />

representative of the Revenue Institutions in Ghana; one representative from the<br />

Ghana Investment Promotion Council; one representative from the Association of<br />

Non-Banking Financial Institutions; one representative of the Bank of Ghana; one<br />

representative of the Ghana Association of Bankers; one representative of the<br />

Association of Ghana Industry; three representatives of the private sector,<br />

nominated by the Private Enterprise Foundation; the Administrator of the<br />

Commercial Court; the Registrar of the Commercial Court and the Director, Judicial<br />

Reform Programme of the Judiciary. The Committee is intended to operate as a<br />

watchdog of the Commercial Court and to liaise between the Court's Management<br />

Committee on the one hand and the Court's users and the general public on the<br />

other.<br />

This institutional framework for a feedback on the work of the Commercial<br />

Court is an interesting model which may repay study for more general incorporation<br />

into the Judicial Service. It is, of course, not intended as a forum for redress or<br />

complaint on individual cases before the Court. There are other avenues in the<br />

Judicial Service for that. Rather, its task is to serve as a channel for mobilizing the<br />

support of the commercial community and the general public in facilitating the<br />

activities of the Commercial Court, while at the same time ensuring that such<br />

community support does not infringe the independence of the judiciary and the<br />

impartiality of the learned Commercial Court judges. This task implies a role in<br />

providing feedback to the administrators of the Commercial Court of community<br />

impressions and reactions to the justice delivered by the Commercial Court.<br />

Reciprocally, the Committee has a role in communicating to the commercial<br />

community and the general public the essence of the concept of a Commercial<br />

Division of the High Court and what may be expected of it and what may not be<br />

expected of it. There should thus be a two-way flow of communication between the<br />

Commercial Court and its stakeholders, with the Users Committee, hopefully,<br />

facilitating this vital interactive process.<br />

The establishment of the Commercial Court in Ghana and its development thus<br />

far are steps in the right direction with regard to the evolution of an appropriate<br />

institutional framework for economic development. While it is still early, it is<br />

already an institutional development worth drawing attention to.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 623 2006-2007


HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 624 2006-2007


Developing Global Transnational<br />

Harmonization Procedures for the Twenty-<br />

First Century: The Accelerating Pace of<br />

Common and Civil <strong>Law</strong> Convergence<br />

Louis F. DEL DUCA<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. PROCEDURAL OPTIONS -THE NEW CHALLENGE .......................................... 626<br />

A. General Considerations - Key Actors - Selecting Harmonization<br />

A reas and P rocedures ................................................................................. 627<br />

B. Conventions: CISG and European Convention on Human Rights ........ 629<br />

C . M o d el L a w s ................................................................................................. 63 1<br />

D . G u id elin es ................................................................................................... 63 1<br />

E. Voluntary Contractual Applicability Texts: Incoterms, Uniform<br />

Customs and Practices, Arbitration Rules ................................................ 632<br />

F. Use of Regulations, Directives, and 'Mutual Recognition' Procedures<br />

in the E uropean U nion ............................................................................... 633<br />

G. Use of Conventions, Recommendations, and Exchange of Views in<br />

the C ouncil of E urope ................................................................................. 637<br />

H . A chieving Uniform ity in Practice .............................................................. 638<br />

II. SPECIFIC H ARMONIZATION A REAS .................................................................. 641<br />

A . Case <strong>Law</strong> as a Source of <strong>Law</strong> .................................................................... 641<br />

1. The "Goodhart" and "Zweigert-K6tz-Cappelletti" Eras and<br />

Entry into the Third M illennium ........................................................ 641<br />

2. G oodhart E ra ........................................................................................ 642<br />

3. Zweigert-K otz-Cappelletti Era ........................................................... 642<br />

4. Entry into the Third M illennium ........................................................ 645<br />

5. Experience of Constitutional Courts in Europe and Case <strong>Law</strong> in<br />

C ivil L aw System s ................................................................................. 646<br />

6. Case <strong>Law</strong> Experience of the European Union: An Example of<br />

Civil and Common <strong>Law</strong> Convergence in Practice ............................ 647<br />

7. Other Perspectives: The Role of Precedent in Mexico .................... 648<br />

B. Status of Selected Current Substantive Harmonization Projects ............. 650<br />

1. Principles of European Contract <strong>Law</strong> ................................................ 650<br />

2. E uropean C ivil C ode ............................................................................ 651<br />

3. UNIDROIT Principles 2004: A Further Step Toward a Global<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 625 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

C ontract L aw ........................................................................................ 654<br />

4. G lobal Com m ercial Code .................................................................... 655<br />

5. Other International Regimes' Impact on Convergence:<br />

UNCITRAL and the World Trade Organization ............................. 656<br />

C. Principles and Rules of Transnational Civil Procedure - An ALl and<br />

UNIDROIT Cooperative Harmonization Project ................................... 657<br />

D. Impact of Electronic International Reporting Systems on<br />

C on vergen ce ................................................................................................. 659<br />

I. PROCEDURAL OPTIONS - THE NEW CHALLENGE<br />

Transnational harmonization results from either planned changes in legal<br />

systems aimed at achieving harmonization or from interaction that spontaneously<br />

occurs between different legal systems. The latter phenomenon may be described as<br />

'osmotic' harmonization.<br />

Unique challenges and opportunities were presented to comparative and<br />

international lawyers after the transition year of 1990 generated by the collapse of<br />

the Soviet system. With the twenty-first century upon us, the globalization of the<br />

world economy continues unabated and profound geopolitical changes continue to<br />

simultaneously occur.<br />

European developments by themselves suggest the vast scope of the changes<br />

involved. The phenomenon of Eastern European countries and the former republics<br />

of the former Soviet Union moving from controlled to free economies and<br />

developing multi-party democratic governments is only an example of these changes.<br />

The unification of Germany also generated a wave of public and private comparative<br />

and international legal problems all demanding instant attention. Massive<br />

privatization and democratization issues had to be addressed. More recently the<br />

effort of the European Union to implement a constitution for twenty-five member<br />

states, with twenty-one different languages, over four hundred fifty million people,<br />

and individual national cultural traditions, continue to require coordination of the<br />

legal systems of the member states.<br />

Commenting as early as 1978 on the pervasive importance of Community <strong>Law</strong><br />

to member states, Lord Denning stated:<br />

... all this shows that the flowing tide of Community <strong>Law</strong> is coming in fast.<br />

It has not stopped at the high water mark. It has broken the dykes and the<br />

banks. It has submerged the surrounding land. So much so that we have<br />

to learn to become amphibious if we wish to keep heads above the water.<br />

What do such developments mean for comparative lawyers? A plethora of<br />

constitutional and administrative (that is, taxation, environmental law, labor law,<br />

social security, and so on) public law issues arose as new governments were created<br />

or old governments were restructured. Simultaneously a plethora of private law<br />

issues arose with the use of new trading entities and new contract procedures as free<br />

economies replaced controlled economies. These issues have generated rethinking<br />

1. Shields v. E. Coomes Holding Ltd., (1978) 1 W.L.R. 1408, 1416 (A.C.) (Eng.).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 626 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 627<br />

of traditional categories of international and comparative law. A half century ago<br />

Phillip Jessup stated:<br />

The subject to which these chapters are addressed is the law applicable to<br />

the complex interrelated world community which may be described as<br />

beginning with the individual and reaching on up to the so called "family<br />

of nations" or "society of states". . . Part of the difficulty in analyzing the<br />

problems of the world community and the law regulating them is the lack<br />

of an appropriate word or term for the rules we are discussing. Just as the<br />

word "international" is inadequate to describe the problem, so the term<br />

"international law" will not do .... I shall use, instead of "international<br />

law", the term "transnationa law" to include all law which regulates actions<br />

or events that transcend national frontiers. Both public and private<br />

internationalaw are included, as are other rules which do not wholly fit into<br />

such standard categories.'<br />

Are the traditional techniques and categories of law for producing harmonized<br />

international legislation responsive to the needs of the twenty-first century?<br />

A. General Considerations - Key Actors - Selecting Harmonization Areas and<br />

Procedures<br />

Primary actors in the process of producing transnational harmonized legislation<br />

such as the Hague Conference, 3 UNIDROIT, 4 UNCITRAL, the International<br />

Chamber of Commerce, 6 the Council of Europe, 7 the European Union," and so on,<br />

2. PHILLIP C. JESSUP, TRANSNATIONAL LAW 2-3 (1956)(emphasis added).<br />

3. Willis L. M. Reese, The Hague Conference on Private International <strong>Law</strong>, 19 Int'l L.. 881, 881 (1985);<br />

Kurt H. Nadelmann, The United <strong>State</strong>s Joins the Hague Conference on Private International <strong>Law</strong>, 30 <strong>Law</strong> &<br />

Contemp. Probs. 291, 291-92 (1965).<br />

4. UNIDROIT is composed of sixty-one member states, namely: Argentina, Australia, Austria,<br />

Belgium, Bolivia, Brazil, Bulgaria, Canada, Chile, China, Columbia, Croatia, Cuba, Cyprus, Czech<br />

Republic, Denmark, Egypt, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Holy See, Hungary, India, Iran,<br />

Iraq, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Latvia, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Malta, Mexico, The Netherlands,<br />

Nicaragua, Nigeria, Norway, Pakistan, Paraguay, Poland, Portugal, Republic of Korea, Romania, Russian<br />

Federation, San Marino, Serbia and Montenegro, Slovakia, Slovenia, South Africa, Spain, Sweden,<br />

Switzerland, Tunisia, Turkey, the U.K., the U.S., Uruguay, Venezuela, available at<br />

http://www.unidroit.org/english/members/main.htm. Over a period of eighty years, UNIDROIT has<br />

engaged in many significant projects such as preparatory work for the United Nations Convention on<br />

Contracts for the International Sale of Goods. See JOHN 0. HONNOLD, UNIFORM LAW FOR<br />

INTERNATIONAL SALES UNDER 1980 UNITED NATIONS CONVENTION (1982); M. J. Bonell, The<br />

UNIDROIT Initiative for the Progressive Codification of International Trade <strong>Law</strong>, 27 INT'L & COMP. L. Q.<br />

413 (1978).<br />

5. Gerold Herrmann, The Contribution of UNCITRA L to the Development of International Trade<br />

<strong>Law</strong>, in 2 THE TRANSNATIONAL LAW OF INTERNATIONAL COMMERCIAL TRANSACTIONS (Norbert Horn<br />

& Cliver M. Schmitthoff eds., 1982).<br />

6. The International Chamber of Commerce was formed in Paris on June 24, 1920. International<br />

Chamber of Commerce, World Peace Through World Trade - ICC 1919 - 1979 4 (1979).<br />

7. The Council of Europe is a political intergovernmental organization. Its permanent headquarters<br />

are in Strasbourg, France. It represents forty-six European pluralist democracies, with five observers<br />

(Canada, the Holy See, Japan, Mexico and the United <strong>State</strong>s of America). The aims of the Council are: to<br />

protect human rights and the rule of law in all member states; to consolidate democratic stability in Europe<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 627 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

have attempted to identify the need for proposed legislation and the likelihood of its<br />

acceptance and adoption before allocating limited resources to such projects. These<br />

organizations have generally avoided the pitfalls created in attempting to harmonize<br />

areas of law primarily to achieve logical symmetry or to achieve limited purposes not<br />

important to a sufficiently large base of proponents. They have instead first<br />

generally established real need for the harmonization project and the existence of<br />

proponents and a climate likely to assure acceptance of the finished product.<br />

After completing the process of identifying an area for preparation of<br />

harmonized transnational legislation, a choice must be made regarding the form,<br />

which such legislation should take. Traditional techniques involve use of<br />

Conventions or Model <strong>Law</strong>s. However, effective use has been made of other<br />

techniques involving preparation of (1) restatements of principles or uniform<br />

practices which contracting parties may incorporate into their contracts, or (2)<br />

publication of "Guidelines" which can be consulted by contracting parties in drafting<br />

by backing political, legal, and constitutional reform nationally, regionally and locally; to seek solutions to<br />

social problems such as intolerance, discrimination against minorities, human cloning, drugs, terrorism,<br />

corruption, and organized crime: to promote and develop a European cultural identity, with special<br />

emphasis on education; and to promote social cohesion and social rights. The structure of the Council of<br />

Europe is as follows: The Committee of Ministers, the decision-making body, comprising the Foreign<br />

Ministers of the forty-six member states or their permanent diplomatic representatives; The Parliamentary<br />

Assembly, the deliberative body, grouping 315 members (and 315 substitutes) from the 46 national<br />

parliaments and delegations from non-member states The Congress of Local and Regional Authorities of<br />

the Council of Europe - two chambers, one for local and one for regional authorities; The European Court<br />

of Human Rights, based in Strasbourg, permanently in session and dealing with all procedures from<br />

admissibility to final judgment. The Parliamentary Assembly elects judges for a six-year term. The Treaty<br />

of London, establishing the Council of Europe, was signed on May 5, 1949 by ten states, namely: Belgium,<br />

Denmark, France, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, and the U.K. See<br />

http://www.coe.int/T/E/Com/AboutCoe/Brochures/At-a-glance.asp.<br />

8. The European Union (European Community) is composed of twenty-five member states, namely:<br />

Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Cyprus, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece,<br />

Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Luxemburg, Malta, the Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Slovakia,<br />

Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, and the UK. Initially formed with the Treaty Establishing the European<br />

Community (previously known as European Economic Community - EEC), which was signed in Rome on<br />

March 25, 1957, followed by Treaty on European Union, signed in Maastricht in 1992 and then followed by<br />

amendments in both Treaties by the Treaty of Amsterdam in 1997 and the Treaty of Nice in 2001. In June<br />

2004, a Treaty Establishing a Constitution for Europe was adopted and on October 29, 2004 was signed by<br />

the heads of state of each Member Country and the three candidate countries (Bulgaria, Romania and<br />

Turkey). It is currently undergoing ratification process in the member states. For more information and<br />

text of the Treaty, see Towards a Eurropean Constitution, http://europa.eu.int/constitution/indexen.htm.<br />

The Council of the European Union (formerly known as the Council of Ministers of the European<br />

Community) is the Union's main decision-making institution. Each member state presides over the<br />

Council for a six-month period on a rotational basis. Every Council meeting is attended by one minister<br />

from each of the member states. Which ministers attend a meeting depends on which topic is on the<br />

agenda. It is composed of the twenty-five member states, namely: Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic,<br />

Cyprus, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania,<br />

Luxemburg, Malta, The Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, and the U.K.<br />

The Council meets in nine different configurations. The preparatory work for Council meetings is done by<br />

the Permanent Representatives Committee (Coreper), made up of the member states' ambassadors to the<br />

EU, assisted by officials from the national ministries. Decision-making in the European Union involves<br />

the European Commission, the European Parliament and the Council. The European Commission<br />

proposes new legislation, but it is the Council and Parliament that pass the laws. There are three main<br />

procedures for enacting new EU laws: co-decision; consultation; and assent. The main difference between<br />

them is the way Parliament interacts with the Council. Under the consultation procedure, Parliament<br />

merely gives its opinion; under the co-decision procedure Parliament genuinely shares power with the<br />

Council. See The Union's Decision Making Procedures, [hereinafter Union Decision Making Procedures],<br />

http://europa.eu/scadplus/europeanconvention/procedures-en.htm.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 628 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 629<br />

contracts. Use of "recommendations" and "exchange of views" by the Council of<br />

Europe should also be noted.<br />

B. Conventions: CISG and European Convention on Human Rights<br />

Preparation of international rules in the form of conventions requires states to<br />

ratify or accede to language identical to the terms of the convention, subject only to<br />

reservations, which the convention might permit. If properly administered and<br />

interpreted a convention provides uniformity and predictability for contracting<br />

parties.<br />

The United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of<br />

Goods (CISG), ratified by sixty-seven states as of June 7, 2006, " ) is one of the major<br />

9. United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods, Apr. 10, 1980, 1489<br />

U.N.T.S. 3, available at http://www.uncitral.org/en-index.htm. The Convention entered into force on Jan. 1,<br />

1988. For a lengthy inclusive bibliography of the voluminous literature on the CISG, see<br />

http://cisgw3.law.pace.edu/cisg/biblio/biblio.html. For a selected list of materials on the CISG, see THE<br />

DRAFT UNCITRAL DIGEST AND BEYOND: CASES, DECISIONS, AND UNRESOLVED ISSUES IN THE U.N.<br />

SALES CONVENTION (Franco Ferrari, Harry Flechtner & Ronald Brand eds., 2004) (the final text of the<br />

UNCITRAL Digest may be found at http://cisgw3.law.pace.edu/cisg/text/digest-toc.html-an update of the<br />

digest is pending); COMMENTARY ON THE UN CONVENTION ON THE INTERNATIONAL SALE OF GOODS<br />

(CISG) (Peter Schlechtriem & lngeborg Schwenzer eds., 2d ed. 2005); HERBERT BERNSTEIN & JOSHEPH<br />

LOOKOFSKY UNDERSTANDING THE CISG IN EUROPE (2d ed. 2004); JOHN 0. HONNOLD, UNIFORM LAW<br />

FOR INTERNATIONAL SALES UNDER THE 1980 UNITED NATIONS CONVENTION (3d ed. 1999): ALBERT H.<br />

KRITZER GUIDE TO PRACTICAL APPLICATIONS OF THE UNITED NATIONS CONVENTION ON CONTRACTS<br />

FOR THE INTERNATIONAL SALE OF GOODS (1993-95)(an updated edition co-edited with Ziegfried Eiselen<br />

is pending). On March 15-18, 2006, UNCITRAL convened a symposium marking the twenty-fifth<br />

anniversary of the CISG featuring thirty-seven CISG scholars evaluating and updating case law reported in<br />

the UNCITRAL Digest. For papers presented at this meeting, see 25 J. L. & COM. 1 and 25 J. L. & COM. 2<br />

10. L. Del Duca & P. Del Duca, The New Convention on the International Sale of Goods - An<br />

Introductory Primer for Attorneys and International Traders, COMP. L. ANN. 553, 556 (1991). The<br />

Convention was unanimously approved by a diplomatic conference of sixty-two states in Vienna on Apr.<br />

11, 1980. UN Doc. A/Conf. 97/18, reprinted in 19 International Legal Materials 668 (1980). L. Del Duca<br />

and P. Del Duca, Practice Under the Convention on International Sale of Goods (CISG): A Primer for<br />

Attorneys and International Traders (Part 1), 27 UCC L.J. 331 (1995), L. Del Duca and P. Del Duca,<br />

Practice Under the Convention on International Sale of Goods (CISG): A Primer for Attorneys and<br />

International Traders (Part 11) 29 UCC L.J. 99 (1996). The seventy states which have ratified the<br />

Convention as of February 20, 2007 include Argentina (July 19, 1983), Australia (Mar. 17, 1988), Austria<br />

(Dec. 29, 1987), Belarus (Oct. 9, 1989), Belgium (Oct. 31, 1996), Bosnia and Herzegovina (Jan. 12, 1994),<br />

Bulgaria (July 9, 1990), Burundi (Sept. 4, 1998), Canada (Apr. 23, 1991), Chile (Feb. 7. 1990), China (Dec.<br />

11, 1986), Colombia (July 10, 2001), Croatia (June 8, 1998), Cuba (Nov. 2, 1994), Cyprus (Mar. 7, 2005),<br />

Czech Republic (Sept. 30, 1993), Denmark (Feb. 14, 1989), Ecuador (Jan. 27, 1992), El Salvador (Nov. 27,<br />

2006), Egypt (Dec. 6, 1982), Estonia (Sept. 20 1993). Finland (Dec. 15, 1987). France (Aug. 6, 1982), Gabon<br />

(Dec. 15, 2004), Georgia (Aug. 16, 1994), Germany (Dec. 21, 1989), Ghana (signed on Apr. 11, 1980;not yet<br />

ratified), Greece (Jan. 12, 1998), Guinea (Jan. 23, 1991), Honduras (Oct. 10, 2002), Hungary (June 16,<br />

1983), Iceland (May 10, 2001), Iraq (Mar. 5, 1990), Israel (Jan. 22, 2002), Italy (Dec. 11, 1986), Kyrgyzstan<br />

(May 11, 1999), Latvia (July 31, 1997), Lesotho (June 18, 1981), Liberia (Sept. 16, 2005), Lithuania (Jan. 18,<br />

1995), Luxemburg (Jan. 30, 1997), the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia (Nov. 22, 2006).<br />

Mauritania (Aug. 20, 1999), Mexico (Dec. 29, 1987), Mongolia (Dec. 31, 1997), Montenegro (Oct. 23,<br />

2006), Netherlands (Dec. 13, 1990), New Zealand (Sept. 22. 1994), Norway (July 20, 1988), Paraguay (Jan.<br />

13, 2006), Peru (Mar. 25, 1999), Poland (May 19, 1995), Republic of Korea (Feb. 17, 2004), Moldova (Oct.<br />

13, 1994), Romania (May 22, 1991). Russian Federation (Aug. 16, 1990). Saint Vincent and the Grenadines<br />

(Sept. 12, 2000), Serbia (Mar. 12, 2001), Singapore (Feb. 16, 1995), Slovakia (May 28, 1993), Slovenia (Jan.<br />

7, 1994), Spain (July 24, 1990). Sweden (Dec. 15. 1987), Switzerland (Feb. 21, 1990), Syrian Arab Republic<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 629 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

harmonization achievements involving use of the convention technique. It is worth<br />

noting that over a period of more than fifty years, three major organizations (that is,<br />

UNIDROIT, the Hague Conference, and UNCITRAL) were involved in gradually<br />

developing the consensus required for its preparation." The advantages of<br />

harmonizing such text and the resulting facilitation of achieving certainty and<br />

predictability in the law governing sales transactions are obvious. However, the<br />

more than half-century required to achieve consensus on the text is a matter of<br />

concern. Future demands for operative uniform rules may not afford the luxury of<br />

such a long lead-time between conception and finalization of projects.<br />

Another example of how the convention technique could be used for achieving<br />

harmonization is the European Convention on Human Rights. 2 It was adopted<br />

under the auspices of the Council of Europe and established the first international<br />

legal instrument safeguarding human rights. 3<br />

The European Court of Human Rights was established with the Convention.' 4<br />

Any person who feels their rights have been violated under the Convention by a<br />

state party can take a case to the Court. 5 The decisions of the Court are legally<br />

binding and the Court has the power to award damages. <strong>State</strong> Parties can also take<br />

cases against other <strong>State</strong> Parties to the Court, although this power is rarely used.<br />

The Convention has five main sections. The main rights and freedoms are<br />

contained in Section I, which consists of Articles 2 to 18.16 Originally, Section II<br />

(Article 19) set up the Commission and the Court, Sections III (Articles 20 to 37)<br />

and IV (Articles 38 to 59) included the high-level machinery for the operation of,<br />

respectively, the Commission and the Court, and Section V contained various<br />

concluding provisions. 7 Many of the Articles in Section I are structured in two<br />

paragraphs: the first sets out a basic right or freedom (such as Article 2(1) - the right<br />

to life) but the second contains various exclusions, exceptions or limitations on the<br />

basic right (such as Article 2(2) - which excepts certain uses of force leading to<br />

death). 8<br />

The Convention has been amended several times by means of protocols. The<br />

protocols required universal ratification to enter into force, in order to maintain the<br />

institutional unity of the Convention machinery. For example, prior to the entry into<br />

(Oct. 19, 1982), Uganda (Feb. 12, 1992), Ukraine (Jan. 3, 1990), United <strong>State</strong>s of America (Dec. 11, 1986).<br />

Uruguay (Jan. 25, 1999), Uzbekistan (Nov. 27, 1996), Venezuela (signed on Sept. 28, 1981; have not ratified<br />

yet), Zambia (June 6. 1986), available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.orgluncitral/en/uncitral-texts/sale-goods/1980CISG-status.htm.<br />

11. L. Del Duca and P. Del Duca, supra note 10 ('The Secretary-General of the United Nations is<br />

hereby designated as the depository for this Convention"); L. Del Duca and P. Del Duca, Practice Under<br />

the Convention on International Sale of Goods (CISG): A Primer for Attorneys and International Traders<br />

(Part 1) 27 UCC L.J. 331 (1995); L. Del Duca and P. Del Duca, Practice Under the Convention on<br />

International Sale of Goods (CISG): A Primer for Attorneys and International Traders (Part I1) 29 UCC<br />

L.J. 99 (1996).<br />

12. See The Council of Europe Convention for the Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental<br />

Freedoms was signed in Rome on Nov. 4, 1950, [hereinafter Coucil of Europe Convention], available at<br />

http://conventions.coe.int/Treaty/en/Treaties/Html/005 .htm.<br />

13. For an overview discussion of the creation and structure of the Council of Europe, see supra note<br />

7; infra note 59.<br />

14. Coucil of Europe Convention, supra note 12, art 19.<br />

15. Id. arts. 34-35.<br />

16. Id. arts. 2-18.<br />

17. Id.<br />

18. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 630 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 631<br />

force of Protocol 11, individuals did not have direct access to the Court; they had to<br />

apply to the European Commission on Human Rights, which if it found the case to<br />

be well-founded would launch a case in the Court on the individual's behalf.<br />

Protocol 11 abolished the Commission, enlarged the Court, and allowed individuals<br />

to take cases directly to it.<br />

However, in some instances fundamental, irreconcilable differences in national<br />

legal systems may mandate use of a model law rather than a convention<br />

harmonization process.<br />

C. Model <strong>Law</strong>s<br />

In 1985, UNCITRAL adopted a <strong>Law</strong> on International Commercial Arbitration<br />

as a model law rather than a convention.' 9 Legislation based on it has been enacted<br />

in Australia, Azerbaijan, Bahrain, Bangladesh, Belarus, Bermuda, Bulgaria, Canada,<br />

Chile, in China: Hong Kong Special Administrative Region, Macau Special<br />

Administrative Region; Croatia, Cyprus, Egypt, Germany, Greece, Guatemala,<br />

Hungary, India, Iran (Islamic Republic of), Ireland, Japan, Jordan, Kenya,<br />

Lithuania, Madagascar, Malta, Mexico, New Zealand, Nigeria, Oman, Paraguay,<br />

Peru, Republic of Korea, Russian Federation, Singapore, Spain, Sri Lanka, Thailand,<br />

Tunisia, Ukraine, parts of the United Kingdom (the overseas territory of Bermuda<br />

and Scotland); five states of the United <strong>State</strong>s: California, Connecticut, Illinois,<br />

Oregon and Texas; Zambia, and Zimbabwe." Since it is a model law, legislative<br />

bodies of the enacting states can therefore enact it as is, or with changes. This<br />

flexibility gives states enacting model laws the option of incorporating changes they<br />

deem desirable. In addition, in contrast to cumbersome procedures needed to<br />

modify a convention, future changes can be made as needed in a model law simply<br />

by using the existing normal legislative process of the enacting state.<br />

D. Guidelines<br />

Use of the Guidelines procedure is illustrated by the UNCITRAL Legal Guide<br />

on Drawing Up International Contracts for the Construction f Industrial Works. 2<br />

These Guidelines are neither a set of rules nor of principles. They are instead a<br />

systematic treatment of matters to be addressed in large-scale construction contracts,<br />

with specific suggestions on the matter in which they may be treated. Evidence thus<br />

far available on the use of the Guidelines indicates that they are particularly helpful<br />

to developing countries involved in large-scale construction contracting.<br />

19. Report of United Nations Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong> on the Work of Its Eighteenth<br />

Session, 40 GAOR Supp. (No. 17), U.N. Doc. A/40/17 (1985).<br />

20. See UNCITRAL Web Site, http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/index.html. Also, updated<br />

information can be obtained by contacting the Treaty Section of the United Nations Office of Legal<br />

Affairs, available at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/uncitraltexts/arbitration/1985Modelarbitration status.html.<br />

21. See U.N. Publication (1988), A/CN9/Scv. B/2; Basmayable, The Work of UNCITRAL in the Field<br />

of Industrial Contracts, The International Construction <strong>Law</strong> Review 273 (1989), at<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/en-index.htm.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 631 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

E. Voluntary Contractual Applicability Texts: Incoterms, Uniform Customs and<br />

Practices, Arbitration Rules<br />

The UNIDROIT project on Principles of International Contracts involved<br />

preparation of a Restatement of international contract law. 22 This project fulfilled<br />

several practical needs. Professor Joachim Bonell has noted that the Principles can<br />

elaborate general principles and rules relating to the law of contract in order to<br />

provide the necessary legal environment for the interpretation of uniform laws<br />

governing special types of transactions. 23 He noted that harmonization of specific<br />

areas of law such as sale of goods, negotiable instruments, modes of transport,<br />

intellectual property, and so on had been effective on a sectoral basis. 24 However, as<br />

discussed by Ren6 David, the limited nature of unification poses the problem of how<br />

to use national rules and techniques which have escaped unification to supplement<br />

uniform law. 25 The Principles supplement areas of law, which have been harmonized<br />

on sectoral basis.<br />

The Principles also serve as a guideline for national legislative bodies<br />

(particularly in developing countries) in enacting a basic code of contract law. In<br />

addition, having been prepared by a prestigious independent international<br />

organization in co-operation with a broad base of other academic, governmental,<br />

and private groups, parties to international contacts may see fit to incorporate the<br />

Principles into their contracts as applicable law even though they might not be<br />

enacted as legislation.<br />

Widespread recognition and use of rules drafted by respected and prestigious<br />

international organizations on a voluntary basis by contracting parties is an<br />

important source of harmonized international rules. This procedure is further<br />

exemplified by the International Chamber of Commerce through its Incoterms 26 and<br />

Letter of Credit Uniform Customs and Practices. 2 Similarly, the much used 1976<br />

UNCITRAL 'Arbitration Rules' offer parties the option of making applicable a<br />

carefully prepared set of arbitration rules to initiate a private arbitration process, in<br />

lieu of utilizing institutional arbitration offered by organizations such as the<br />

International Chamber of Commerce, American Arbitration Association, and other<br />

institutionalized arbitration centers in major cities of the world. 8<br />

This voluntary application technique is an alternative procedure by which<br />

parties have achieved order and predictability in their international contracting. The<br />

22. UNIDROIT Principles: A New Edition of the UNIDROIT Principles for International<br />

Commercial Contracts (2004), available at http://www.unidroit.org/english/principles/contracts/main.htm.<br />

23. Michael Joachim Bonell, UNIDROIT Principles 2004 - The New Edition of the Principles of<br />

International Commercial Contracts adopted by the International Institute for the Unification of Private<br />

<strong>Law</strong>, 9 UNIF. L. REV. 5 (2004).<br />

24. See Michael Joachim Bonell, A "Restatement" of Principles for International Commercial<br />

Contracts: An Academic Exercise or A Practical Need?, 7 INT'L Bus. L. J. 873 (1988).<br />

25. Ren6 David, The International Unification of Private <strong>Law</strong>, in 2 INTERNATIONAL ENCYCLOPEDIA<br />

OF COMPARATIVE LAW ch. 5 at 123-24 (Ren6 David et al. eds., 1971).<br />

26. International Chamber of Commerce (ICC) INCOTERMS, 22 Y.B. INT'L L. COMM'N 399, U.N.<br />

Doc. A/CN.9/348.<br />

27. See ICC Banking Commission, UCP 1974/1983 REVISIONS COMPARED AND EXPLAINED:<br />

DOCUMENTARY CREDITS (1984).<br />

28. Report of United Nations Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong> on the Work of Its Ninth<br />

Session, 31 U.N. GAOR Supp. (No. 17) para. 57, U.N. Doc A/31/17 (1976).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 632 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 633<br />

'Principles of International Contracts' provide an additional source of orderly<br />

contract rules for interested parties.<br />

F<br />

Use of Regulations, Directives, and 'Mutual Recognition' Procedures in the<br />

European Union<br />

The artificial cleavage often made between public and private law<br />

harmonization efforts is blurred by the intensely pragmatic work of the European<br />

Community 9 and the Council of Europe (with its historic European Convention on<br />

Human Rights" and its many private law accomplishments). The framework of the<br />

Union, initially provided by the 1957 Treaty of Rome 3 was later amended by the<br />

Maastricht Treaty 32 (subsequent amendments followed with the Treaty of<br />

Amsterdam in 1997 and the Treaty of Nice in 2001). In October 2004 a Treaty<br />

Establishing a Constitution for Europe was signed. The ratification process<br />

continued with ten states having ratified the constitution prior to the negative votes<br />

in the referendum in France on May 29, 2005 and in Holland on June 1, 2006. No<br />

further action has been taken subsequent to these negative votes. 33 The treaties<br />

create a unique division of legislative, executive, and judicial powers, which<br />

facilitates the effective use of the Union's institutions for achieving harmonization or<br />

unification of legislation in areas where the Union has power (i.e. competence).<br />

Under the current treaties, the European Commission has executive power coupled<br />

with the power to initiate legislative proposals. 34 Its primary roles are to propose and<br />

enact legislation, and to act as guardian of the treaties. It currently consists of<br />

twenty-five Commissioners, one from each member state. Each Commissioner takes<br />

responsibility for a particular area of policy, and heads a department called a<br />

Directorate General. The Commission is headed by a President." The Council is<br />

the Union's main decision-making body. The main roles of the Parliament are to<br />

share with the Council the power to legislate, to exercise democratic supervision<br />

over all EU institutions, in particular the Commission, and it to authorize the budget<br />

together with the Council.<br />

Much of the EU legislation is adopted jointly by the Council and Parliament.<br />

As a rule, the Council only acts on a proposal from the Commission, and the<br />

Commission normally has responsibility for ensuring that EU legislation, once<br />

adopted, is correctly applied. The rules and procedures for EU decision-making 36<br />

are laid down in the treaties. Every European law is based on a specific treaty<br />

29. The Treaty on European Union signed on Feb. 7, 1992 in Maastricht between the members of the<br />

European Community led to the creation of the European Union. The Maastricht Treaty, Feb. 7, 1992,<br />

1992 O.J. (C191) 1. The European Community now constitutes one of the "three pillars" of the European<br />

Union.<br />

30. See European Convention on Human Rights, reprinted in INTERNATIONAL HUMAN RIGHTS<br />

INSTRUMENTS, 500.1-500.17 (Richard B. Lillich ed., 2d ed. 1990).<br />

31. See Treaty of Rome Establishing the European Economic Community, Mar. 25, 1957, 298<br />

U.N.T.S. 79.<br />

32. See The Maastricht Treaty, supra note 29.<br />

33. See supra note 8 and accompanying text. See also http://europa.eu.int/constitution/indexen.htm.<br />

34. The term "the Commission" is generally used to refer both to the administrative body in its<br />

entirety, and to the team of Commissioners who lead it.<br />

35. As of Nov. 2004, the President is Jos6 Manuel Dur~o Barroso of Portugal.<br />

36. See Union Decision Making Procedures, supra note 8.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 633 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

article, referred to as the "legal basis" of the legislation. 7 The main procedures for<br />

enacting new EU laws are co-decision, consultation, and assent. The main difference<br />

between them is the way Parliament interacts with the Council. As a rule the<br />

European Commission proposes new legislation, but it is the Council and Parliament<br />

that pass the laws.<br />

The most common legislative procedure in the Union is so called "codecision."<br />

38 Under the co-decision procedure, the Parliament and the Council share<br />

legislative power. The Commission sends its proposal to both institutions. They<br />

each read and discuss it twice in succession. If they cannot agree on it, it is put<br />

before a "conciliation committee," composed of equal numbers of Council and<br />

Parliament representatives.<br />

Under the consultation procedure, the Commission sends its proposal to both<br />

the Council and Parliament, but it is the Council that officially consults Parliament<br />

and other bodies. 9 In some cases, consultation is compulsory because the legal basis<br />

requires it, and the proposal cannot become law unless Parliament has given its<br />

opinion. In other cases consultation is optional and the Commission will simply<br />

suggest that the Council consult Parliament. In all cases, Parliament has the option<br />

of approving the Commission proposal, or rejecting it, or asking for amendments.<br />

Under the assent procedure the Council has to obtain the European<br />

Parliament's assent before certain very important decisions are taken. 40 The<br />

procedure is the same as in the case of consultation, except that Parliament cannot<br />

amend a proposal. It must either accept or reject it. The acceptance (assent)<br />

requires an absolute majority of the vote cast.<br />

The European Union has a unique system of internal law that has direct effect<br />

within the legal systems of its member states. The sources of Union law 1 are the<br />

primary legislation-the treaties, the secondary legislation 2 -regulations, directives,<br />

decisions, recommendations and opinions made by the Union's institutions in<br />

accordance with the treaties, and the decisions of the European Court of Justice and<br />

the Court of First Instance.<br />

37. See Consolidated Version of the Treaty Establishing the European Community art. 253, Dec. 12,<br />

2002, 2002 O.J. (C 325) 135 [hereinafter EC Treaty].<br />

38. See EC Treaty, supra note 32, art. 251. See also Union Decision Making Procedures, supra note 8.<br />

39. See EC Treaty, supra note 32, art. 252. See also Union Decision Making Procedures, supra note 8.<br />

40. See supra note 36.<br />

41. A distinction should be made between European Community law and European Union law, as it<br />

is only European Community law that is held to be dominant over contrary domestic legislation of member<br />

states by the European Court of Justice.<br />

42. See EC Treaty, supra note 32, art. 249. However, under the Treaty Establishing a Constitution for<br />

Europe in Article 1-33 as legal acts of the Union are described European <strong>Law</strong>s, European Framework<br />

<strong>Law</strong>s, European Regulations, European Decisions, Recommendations and Opinions. European <strong>Law</strong>s are<br />

described as legislative acts of general application that are binding in their entirety and directly applicable<br />

in all member states. European Framework <strong>Law</strong>s are described as legislative act binding as to the result to<br />

be achieved upon each member state they are addressed to. They leave to the national authorities the<br />

choice of form and methods for achieving the objectives addressed with the European Framework <strong>Law</strong>s.<br />

European Regulations are non-legislative acts of general application for the implementation of legislative<br />

acts and of certain provisions of the Constitution. They can be either binding in their entirety and directly<br />

applicable in all member states, or be binding as to the result to be achieved upon each member state they<br />

are addressed to but leave the national authorities the choice of form and methods for pursuing the<br />

objectives set in them. European decisions are non-legislative acts binding in their entirety. If they specify<br />

whom they are addressed to, they are binding only on them. Recommendations and opinions have no<br />

binding force. See http://europa.eu.int/constitution/indexen.htm.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 634 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 635<br />

Regulations and directives bind everyone. Regulations have direct effect, i.e.<br />

they are binding as part of the national law, while directives require implementation<br />

in the national legislation in order to be effective. If a member state fails to<br />

implement directives through national law it could be subjected to a financial<br />

sanction by the European Court of Justice. Regulations have a general scope and<br />

are obligatory in all their elements; therefore they are directly applicable in all<br />

member states. Directives, on the other hand, are binding upon each member state<br />

to which they are addressed, but leave to the national authorities the choice of forms<br />

and methods. They allow member states considerable discretion in deciding how to<br />

implement the rules required by the directive. 43<br />

Decisions also have binding effect, but only on the parties to whom they are<br />

addressed, which can be individuals, corporations, or member states.<br />

Recommendations and opinions differ from regulations, directives and<br />

decisions, however, in that they have no binding force and are instruments of<br />

indirect action.<br />

The Union has also developed the important concept of Mutual Recognition. 4<br />

Under this concept, harmonization will be required in areas where health, safety,<br />

environmental, consumer protection, or similar concerns so mandate. Otherwise<br />

standards of each member state will be mutually recognized where national<br />

differences do not jeopardize health, safety, or other paramount concerns.<br />

In 2001 the Commission of the European Community launched a process of<br />

consultation and discussion about the way in which problems resulting from<br />

divergences in national contract laws in the EU should be dealt with at the European<br />

level. Based on this discussions, in 2003 the Commission adopted an action plan<br />

suggesting both regulatory and non-regulatory measures in an attempt to resolve<br />

these problems. 4 " The plan proposes measures to increase the coherence of the EC<br />

acquis in the area of contract law, 46 to promote the elaboration of EU-wide general<br />

contract terms, and to examine further whether problems in the European contract<br />

law area may require non-sector-specific solutions such as an optional instrument. 47<br />

The Commission proposed the establishment of a Common Frame of Reference as<br />

means to achieve an improvement in the contract law acquis4 8 Through the<br />

establishment of common principles and terminology in the area of European<br />

contract law. As a follow up to the 2003 Action Plan, in 2004 the Commission issued<br />

a communication to the European Parliament and the Council. 49<br />

43. EC Treaty, supra note 32, art. 249.<br />

44. The first application of this concept was in the decision of the European Court of Justice 'Casis de<br />

Dijon.' Case 120/78, Rewe-Zentral AG v. Bundesmonopolverwaltung fur Branntwein, 1979 E.C.R. 649.<br />

See Laurence Gormley, Casis de Dijon and Communication from the Commission, EUROPEAN LAW<br />

REVIEW 454 (1981). For an example of the application of the principle by the legislative body, see Council<br />

Resolution of 7 May 1985 on technical harmonization and standards, 1985 O.J. (C 136) 1.<br />

45. Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council, A More<br />

Coherent European Contract <strong>Law</strong>: An Action Plan, COM (2003) 68 final (Feb. 12, 2003) , available at<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/comm/consumers/policy/developments/contract-law/com_2003-68en.pdf.<br />

46. All documents concerning European contract law are available on the Commission's website,<br />

http://europa.eu.int/comm/consumers/cons-int/safe-shop/fair-bus-pract/cont-law/index-en.htm.<br />

47. Rewe-Zentral AG v. Bundesmonopolverwaltung fur Branntwein, 1979 E.C.R. 649.<br />

48. Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council, A More<br />

Coherent European Contract <strong>Law</strong>: An Action Plan, supra note 45, at 15-21.<br />

49. Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament and the Council, European<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 635 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

Harmonization efforts outside of the Union might profit by more careful<br />

definition and delineation of the precise area requiring harmonization and those<br />

areas best left to individual jurisdictions and the principle of mutual recognition.<br />

The great progress made possible by adoption of the harmonization-mutual<br />

recognition process is illustrated by the Union experience in dealing with the matter<br />

of diploma recognition." The partial failure of the sectoral approach to the question<br />

of access and practice to a profession in a member state without any national<br />

discrimination led the Commission to propose a new system based on the general<br />

recognition of diplomas awarded in any member country. As a matter of fact,<br />

previous experience showed that it was not realistic to hope for the free movement<br />

of self-employed persons by continuing to apply the sectoral system. 5 ' Indeed, some<br />

twenty-six years were required to promulgate the directive pertaining to architects. 52<br />

The directive that promotes the general system of recognition of diplomas was<br />

accordingly adopted by the Council on December 21, 1988. Directive 89/48 was to<br />

enter into force at the beginning of 1991.51 It covered all diplomas that were not<br />

affected by 'sectoral' directives already in force, and which were awarded on<br />

completion of a course of higher education at the university level or higher,<br />

comprising at least three years full-time study or the equivalent. Subsequently that<br />

Directive, and several others, were replaced by the Directive 2005/36/EC of the<br />

European Parliament and of the Council of September 7, 2005 on the recognition of<br />

professional qualifications, in OJ (L 255/22) of September 30, 2005.<br />

This system is general in character, that is, it applies to all regulated activities<br />

not covered by sectoral directives. For instance, beneficiaries are teachers,<br />

engineers, opticians, lawyers, and so on. It is based on mutual confidence between<br />

member states and on assumed compatibility between levels of education and<br />

training. When a person is qualified to practice in a member state, having obtained a<br />

diploma and undergone any additional training required, he or she has the right to<br />

access the same profession in any other member state. A diploma obtained in a<br />

third country is accepted if recognized by a member state and supplemented by three<br />

years professional experience in that member state.<br />

In instances of important differences between types of education and training,<br />

the host member state may impose compensatory requirements as follows: (a) If the<br />

difference is more than a year, additional professional experience may be requested,<br />

but must be limited to twice the length of the missing training period; (b) in case of<br />

differences in course content the migrant may choose either an adaptation period of<br />

up to three years under the supervision of a qualified professional, or an aptitude<br />

Contract <strong>Law</strong> and the Revision of the Acquis: The Way Forward, COM (2004) 651 final (Oct. 11, 2004),<br />

available at<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/comm/consumers/cons-int/safe-shop/fair-bus-pract/cont -law/com2004-en.pdf.<br />

50. See Malcolm Ross, Mutual Recognition of Professional Qualifications, 14 EUROPEAN LAW<br />

REVIEW 162, 162 (1989).<br />

51. See Rolf Waegenbaur, Free Movement In The Professions: The New EEC Proposal on<br />

Professional Qualifications, 23 COMMON MKT. L. R. 91. 97-100 (1986).<br />

52. Council Directive 85/384, 1985 O.J (L 223) 15 (EC).<br />

53. See Council Directive 89/48/EEC 1988 O.J. (L 019) 1 (EC), art. 12 (discussing a general system for<br />

the recognition of higher education diplomas awarded on completion of professional education and<br />

training of at least three years' duration).<br />

54. Id. art.1.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 636 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 637<br />

test based on all or some of the missing material." As an exceptional measure, the<br />

host member state may make the choice, and impose an examination for the legal<br />

professions-members of which need a detailed knowledge of national law-and,<br />

with the agreement of the Commission, for other occupations. 5 1<br />

According to Directive 98/5/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council<br />

of February 16, 1998 to facilitate practice of the profession of a lawyer on a<br />

permanent basis in a member state other than that in which the qualification was<br />

obtained, lawyers may become integrated into the profession in the host member<br />

state, as provided for in Directive 89/48/EEC, in the language of the host member<br />

state. No condition of nationality remains. It allows duly qualified EU lawyers<br />

registered with an EU Bar to establish themselves in another member state.<br />

G. Use of Conventions, Recommendations, and Exchange of Views in the Council<br />

of Europe<br />

Conventions, recommendations to governments, and exchanges of views<br />

provide various means of achieving harmonization among the members of the<br />

Council of Europe. The particular means employed depends upon many variables,<br />

including the nature of the change that is desired, the legally binding effect of the<br />

instrument, and the time available to prepare the instrument. An excellent report by<br />

the Council of Europe entitled Methods and Instruments of Co-operation in the<br />

Council discusses the advantages, disadvantages, and circumstances under which<br />

each of these means is utilized."' The need to obtain the requisite number of<br />

ratifications to bring a convention into force and possible extended length of the<br />

preparation phase were noted as possible disadvantages. However, once a<br />

convention is ratified, it has the merit of being legally binding and therefore can have<br />

far-reaching effects. For example, the Council of Europe's historic European<br />

Convention on Human Rights, though a single convention, requires the<br />

constitutional systems of all forty-six member states who have ratified or acceded to<br />

the Convention to conform with the law of human rights set forth in its text. 9<br />

55. Id. art.4.<br />

56. Id. arts. 4, 10.<br />

57. European Parliament and Council Directive 98/5/EC, 1998 O.J. (L 77) 36 (to facilitate practice of<br />

the profession of a lawyer on a permanent basis in a member state other than that in which the<br />

qualification was obtained).<br />

58. The entire subject is reviewed in detail in an excellent article by Ferdinando Albanese, former<br />

Deputy Director of Legal Affairs and current Director of Environmental and Local Authorities, the<br />

Council, at Le Processus Legislative au Conseil de I'Europe. Ferdinando Albanese, Le Processus Ldgislatif<br />

au Conseil de l'Europe, in 3 REVUE TRIMESTRIELLE DE DROIT EUROPEEN 391 (Jan.-Mar. 1986).<br />

59. As of Oct. 2006, the forty-six member states of the Council of Europe are: Albania (July 13, 1995),<br />

Andorra (Nov. 10, 1994), Armenia (Jan. 25, 2001), Austria (Apr. 16, 1956), Azerbaijan (Jan. 25, 2001),<br />

Belgium (May 5, 1949), Bosnia and Herzegovina (Apr. 24, 2002), Bulgaria (May 7, 1992), Croatia (Nov. 6,<br />

1996), Cyprus (May 24, 1961), Czech Republic (June 30, 1993), Denmark (May 5, 1949), Estonia (May 14,<br />

1993), Finland (May 05, 1989), France (May 5, 1949), Georgia (April 27, 1999). Germany (July 13, 1950).<br />

Greece (Aug. 9, 1949), Hungary (Nov. 6, 1990), Iceland (Mar. 7, 1950), Ireland (May 5, 1949), Italy (May 5,<br />

1949), Latvia (Feb. 10, 1995),Liechtenstein (Nov. 23, 1978), Lithuania (May 14, 1993), Luxembourg (May 5,<br />

1949), Malta (Apr. 29, 1965), Moldova (July 13, 1995). Monaco (Oct. 5, 2004). Netherlands (May 5. 1949).<br />

Norway (May 5, 1949). Poland (November 26, 1991), Portugal (September 22, 1976), Romania (Oct. 7.<br />

1993), Russian Federation (Feb. 28, 1996), San Marino (Nov. 16, 1988), Serbia (Apr. 3, 2003), Slovakia<br />

(June 30, 1993), Slovenia (May 14, 1993), Spain (Nov. 24, 1977), Sweden (May 5, 1949), Switzerland (May<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 637 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

Recommendations of the Council of Europe's Committee of Ministers to the<br />

Members are easier to prepare or amend since they are actions of the Committee of<br />

Ministers and no further act of agreement by member states is necessary. However,<br />

while such Recommendations may exert some pressure, the member states are not<br />

required to follow them. The legal duty to act on recommendations goes no further<br />

than to consider in good faith its possible implementation.<br />

Unlike conventions and recommendations, exchanges of views are not<br />

expressly mentioned in the Statute of the Council of Europe. But they are<br />

nevertheless used to produce important practical results. In fact, due to their<br />

informal nature, exchanges of views entail a less arduous drafting process than that<br />

involved in the preparation of convention or recommendation. Generally suitable in<br />

generating discussion of new and unexplored topics or of new problems surfacing in<br />

familiar areas where there is a need to compare opinions and share experiences, they<br />

particularly serve as means to an end, such as development of a convention or a<br />

recommendation to governments.<br />

H. Achieving Uniformity in Practice<br />

Measures will need to be taken to make the transition from successful<br />

convergence of language in uniform acts to actually achieving uniformity in practice.<br />

For example, while the Vienna Sales Convention is a major achievement in adopting<br />

uniform law, problems with achieving uniform application and interpretation of its<br />

provisions are likely. 61 To some extent this is addressed by inclusion of statutory<br />

construction provisions in the convention itself, which attempt to guarantee the<br />

achievement of uniformity in practice. 62 Incorporated into the Convention is the<br />

notion that in the event a problem is not readily answered by the text itself, resort<br />

should be to the principles of the Convention rather than to domestic law for its<br />

resolution. 63 Along with course-of-dealing standards of construction,' usages-oftrade<br />

65 criteria are also built into the Convention-as is a requirement of good faith 6 6<br />

interpretation. While these provisions are helpful and desirable, and may provide<br />

resolutions to some of the problems of achieving uniformity of interpretation in<br />

practice, experience teaches that such uniformity is not easily achieved.<br />

For example, in the United <strong>State</strong>s, we have built into our uniform acts rules of<br />

statutory construction that are comparable to those of the Convention.<br />

Additionally, we have had the benefit of a legal tradition, which is essentially the<br />

same in each of the forty-nine or fifty jurisdictions (Louisiana, which has a civil-law<br />

tradition, excepted). Notwithstanding that we have a core of similarity of tradition<br />

6, 1963),former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia (Sept. 11, 1995), Turkey (Aug. 9, 1949), Ukraine (Sept.<br />

11, 1995), United Kingdom (May 5, 1949). "With effect from 3 June 2006, the Republic of Serbia is<br />

continuing the membership of the Council of Europe previously exercised by the Union of <strong>State</strong>s of Serbia<br />

and Montenegro (CM Decision of 14 June 2006)." Council of Europe Member <strong>State</strong>s, available at<br />

http://www.coe.int/T[E/Com/AboutCoe/Memberstates/default.asp.<br />

60. Council of Europe, available at http://www.coe.int.<br />

61. CISG, supra note 9.<br />

62. Id. arts. 7, 8, 9.<br />

63. Id. art. 7(2).<br />

64. Id. art. 9.<br />

65. Id. art.9.<br />

66. See CISG, supra note 9, art. 7(1).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 638 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 639<br />

in teaching and practicing law and in our sources of law, we have encountered<br />

significant obstacles in achieving uniformity. In part, one of the reasons for<br />

developing the Uniform Commercial Code was the fact that the individual statutes<br />

that preceded it had been interpreted and reinterpreted so many times and so<br />

differently that there was massive confusion as to what they meant. 6 1<br />

The fact that a convention is already in force in states that have different legal<br />

traditions and a variety of techniques and sources of law from which they derive<br />

their principles and canons of construction and usage, creates an even greater<br />

possibility for non-uniform application of identical provisions. 68<br />

Because of these concerns, it is desirable to set in place an institutional<br />

framework to review the manner in which uniform laws are being applied after a<br />

consensus on the text of that uniform law has been adopted.<br />

Experience in the United <strong>State</strong>s teaches that in attempting to restate basic<br />

principles that may be extracted from a large, expanding body of law, it is helpful to<br />

restate the principles in a summary fashion and to indicate the alternatives utilized in<br />

the fifty states. This technique helps to provide a broad outline of available<br />

alternatives. In this way, while restatements are not compulsorily imposed upon any<br />

of the state supreme courts, they nevertheless are available to be considered. If a<br />

preferred view is established, the fact that it is presented after a careful consensusbuilding<br />

approach seeking a recommended solution to the problem may be<br />

persuasive to courts as they interpret the language of a uniform law.<br />

This technique has not been utilized as frequently in the case of uniform acts as<br />

it has with case law in fields such as contracts, conflicts of law, property, and so on.<br />

It has been very helpful in achieving some degree of uniformity in the resolution of<br />

our case law problems. The procedure could also be applied to case-law-interpreting<br />

conventions or model laws. There are several groups presently involved in setting<br />

up reporting services to cover the case law for the Vienna Convention."<br />

When such decisions are collected, efforts should not stop at mere reporting. It<br />

would be of additional benefit if the decisions were systematically objectively<br />

analyzed so that problem areas could be identified and possible preferred<br />

interpretations could be developed. Of course, such interpretations could not be<br />

forced upon any national independent sovereign entity that is working with that<br />

body of law; rather it would be available as a persuasive source of authority as to<br />

what the desirable interpretation should be. 7 "<br />

Non-uniformity in application of European Community <strong>Law</strong> as it is<br />

incorporated into the domestic law of the member states also sometimes develops.<br />

The Union, however, has something working in its favour that is not available in<br />

other types of harmonization efforts. The European Court of Justice possesses the<br />

authority to interpret Union legislation and provide the ultimate legal norm to be<br />

67. See William A. Schnader, Uniform Commercial <strong>Law</strong> - How Soon?, 13 PERS. FIN. L. 68 (1959).<br />

68. See John Henry Merryman, On the Convergence (and Divergence) of the Civil <strong>Law</strong> and the<br />

Common <strong>Law</strong>, 17 STAN. J. INT'L. L. 357,379 (1981).<br />

69. See UNILEX, available at http://www.unilex.info; PACE, available at www.cisg.law.pace.edu;<br />

CLOUIT, available at http://www.un.or.at/uncitral/htm.<br />

70. See id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 639 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

applied. 7 Neither the international community nor the member states of the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s have that kind of centralized authority to resolve such problems.<br />

It is apparent then that in refining our harmonization procedures for future use,<br />

resources need to be allocated to achieving uniformity in practice as well as on the<br />

printed page. The type of institutional framework noted above is one step.<br />

We also need to be continuously sensitive to the quality and quantity of<br />

comparative and international law courses taught in law schools and in continuing<br />

legal education courses in each of our countries.<br />

Expansion of specialized comparative and international law courses and a<br />

programme of supplementing such courses with comparative and international<br />

components to be included in traditional law-school courses is needed.<br />

Development of materials to be used in teaching the content and practice of law<br />

under uniform laws in the law schools of the world and in international seminars for<br />

practicing attorneys, law professors, and judges should complement such a<br />

programme. 7 ' Having harmonized codes or restatements in place does not achieve<br />

harmonization in practice in the absence of competent legal technicians sharing a<br />

common frame of reference and standards, which they can utilize in applying and<br />

interpreting the harmonized language.<br />

71. See PAOLO MENGOZZI, IL DIRITTO DELLA COMUNITA' EUROPEA 88-134 (1990).<br />

72. See Dean R. C. Clark, Building a World <strong>Law</strong> School, 42 HARV. L. BULL. 5 (1991); L. Del Duca,<br />

Comments at pp.141-44, International Uniform <strong>Law</strong> in Practice - Acts and Proceedings of the Third<br />

Congress on Private <strong>Law</strong> Held by the International Institute for the Unification of Private <strong>Law</strong><br />

(UNIDROIT) in Rome, Italy 1987 (1988). Dean Robert C. Clark has also stated "I have reported<br />

previously that we are also planning to become a world law school by including an international facet in<br />

nearly all of our courses . ..," Robert C. Clark, Preparing for the 21st Century, Harvard <strong>Law</strong> School, A<br />

Supplement to the Harvard University Gazette, 7 Dec. 1990, at 1. Evolving implementation of<br />

these early aspirational statements are traced in papers presented in a series of symposia conducted in<br />

recent years at the annual meetings of The Association of American <strong>Law</strong> Schools and subsequently<br />

published. See Symposium, Emerging Worldwide Strategies in Internationalizing Legal Education, 18<br />

DICK. J. INT'L L. 411 (2000); Toni M. Fine, Symposium on Working Together: Developing Cooperation in<br />

International Legal Education, Introduction and Overview, 20 PENN ST. INT'L L. REV. 1 (2001);<br />

Symposium, Working Together: Developing Cooperation in International Legal Education, 20 PENN ST.<br />

INT'L L. REV. 7 (2001); Symposium, Continuing Progress in Internationalizing Legal Education - 21st<br />

Century Global Challenges, 21 PENN ST. INT'L L. REV. 1 (2002); Symposium, Developing Mechanisms to<br />

Enhance Internationalization of Legal Education, 22 PENN ST. INT'L L. REV. 393 (2004); Symposium,<br />

Globalizing Legal Education Symposium: Educating <strong>Law</strong>yers for Transnational Challenges, 23 PENN ST.<br />

INT'L L. REV. 741 (2005); James H. Carter, Transnational <strong>Law</strong>: What Is It?: How Does It Differ from<br />

International <strong>Law</strong> and Comparative <strong>Law</strong>? 23 PENN ST. INT'L L. REV. 797 (Spring 2005); Workshop on<br />

Integrating Transnational Legal Perspectives Into the First Year Curriculum - What Is Transnational <strong>Law</strong><br />

and Why Does It Matter? - Institutional Support and Approaches to Integration, 24 PENN ST. INT'L L. REV.<br />

(forthcoming 2007); Techniques to Internationalize the First Year Curriculum, 24 PENN ST. INT'L L. REV.<br />

(forthcoming 2007).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 640 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 641<br />

II.<br />

SPECIFIC HARMONIZATION AREAS<br />

A. Case <strong>Law</strong> as a Source of <strong>Law</strong><br />

1. The "Goodhart" and "Zweigert-Kotz-Cappelletti" Eras and Entry into<br />

the Third Millennium<br />

In 1934, Arthur Goodhart, the renowned English comparatist, stated that the<br />

fundamental difference between common and civil law was the common law<br />

doctrine of stare decisis, i.e. the binding force of precedent. 73 Konrad Zweigert and<br />

Hein K6tz disputed this fundamental difference advocated by Goodhart. 74 They<br />

argued that the methods of finding law in common and civil law systems were<br />

gradually moving closer together and leading to the same result. 75<br />

Mauro Cappelletti, in a substantially concurring but to some extent dissenting<br />

perspective, maintained that not as much convergence had occurred as Zweigert and<br />

Kotz suggested. He argued that major differences continue to exist between the two<br />

traditions leading to varied precedential weight of case law. 76 Today, some would<br />

contend that convergence has accelerated at an unprecedented rate due to recent<br />

developments in European and International law. In addition, the creation of<br />

constitutional courts in civil law nations has led to a virtually binding force of their<br />

decisions. 77 Additionally, European Union member-states, who originate from both<br />

common and civil law traditions, are collaborating by using aspects of both traditions<br />

to achieve identical goals. Vigorous efforts are also underway to develop a<br />

European Civil Code, a European Contract Code, and even a Global Commercial<br />

Code, which will further advance the convergence of the two traditions.<br />

UNIDROIT has also developed Principles of International Commercial Contracts.<br />

In addition, other international organizations like UNCITRAL and the World Trade<br />

Organization, made up of both common and civil law participants, have contributed<br />

to the accelerating convergence. Harmonization of common and civil procedural law<br />

has also advanced in recent years. The joint project of the American <strong>Law</strong> Institute<br />

and the UNIDROIT Working Group has furthered this harmonization through the<br />

creation of the Principles and Rules of Transnational Civil Procedure. New<br />

technology is also significantly impacting the convergence of common and civil law.<br />

Development of electronic reporting systems, such as those already in existence for<br />

the Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods, will further<br />

facilitate harmonization of legal norms. 6<br />

73. A.L. Goodhart, Precedent in English and Continental <strong>Law</strong>, 50 L. Q. Rev. 40, 42 (1934), in K.<br />

ZWEIGERT ET AL., AN INTRODUCTION TO COMPARATIVE LAW 256, 259 (3d ed. 1998).<br />

74. Seeid.at271.<br />

75. Id.<br />

76. See Mauro Cappelletti, The Doctrine of Stare Decisis and the Civil <strong>Law</strong>: A Fundamental<br />

Difference - or No Difference at All?, Festschrift Zweigert, 387-88 (1981).<br />

77. Id. at 392.<br />

78. United Nations Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong> (UNCITRAL), United Nations<br />

Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods,<br />

http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/uncitral-texts/sale-goods/1980CISG.html.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 641 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

2. Goodhart Era<br />

In 1934, Professor Goodhart discussed the differences between common and<br />

civil law. He believed that the fundamental difference between civil and common<br />

law is the binding force of precedent. 79 The common law doctrine of stare decisis<br />

states that every court is bound by the decisions of courts superior to it in hierarchy. 8 ,<br />

A previous decision is binding even if it was decided a century earlier or if the rule<br />

seems inappropriate. 8 ' There is no equivalent doctrine in civil law; thus, civil law<br />

judges are free to decide each case independently by applying their domestic code<br />

without being bound by previous decisions.<br />

3. Zweigert-K6tz-Cappelletti Era<br />

The era that followed Goodhart produced new practices and customs of<br />

common and civil law. The dependence on case law was greatly reduced in the<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s during the New Deal Era when Congress passed a tremendous<br />

amount of legislation to deal with social problems. Civilian courts, on the other<br />

hand, were developing new practices that began to rely on the persuasive weight of<br />

previous cases. Konrad Zweigert and Hein K6tz believed the doctrine of stare<br />

decisis no longer represented a fundamental difference between the common and<br />

civil law. 82 The methods of finding law in common and civil law generally led to the<br />

same result. 3 Mauro Cappelletti disputed Zweigert and K6tz' analysis and argues<br />

that not as much convergence had taken place as they suggest.8<br />

Based on new practices in common and civil law, Zweigert and Kbtz recognized<br />

that civil and common law methods of finding law were gradually moving closer<br />

together. 5 Despite the existence of the doctrine of stare decisis and the absence of<br />

an equivalent civil law doctrine, the practice of both court systems generally led to<br />

the same result. 6 They stated:<br />

To sum up: on the Continent the days of absolute pre-eminence of<br />

statutory law are past; contrariwise, in the common law there is an<br />

increasing tendency to use legislation in order to unify, rationalize, and<br />

simplify the law. On the Continent, law is increasingly being developed by<br />

the judges and consequently there is more room for an inductive method<br />

and style related to the actual problems; contrariwise, the common law is<br />

seeing the need to bring the rules developed by the judges into systematic<br />

order by means of scholarly analysis and legislative action, so as to make<br />

them easier to understand and master. There are therefore grounds for<br />

believing that although the common law and the civil law started off from<br />

79. Goodhart, supra note 73, at 259.<br />

80. Id.<br />

81. Id. at 260.<br />

82. See id. at 271.<br />

83. Id. at 263.<br />

84. Mauro Cappelletti, The Doctrine of Stare Decisis and the Civil <strong>Law</strong>: A Fundamental Difference -<br />

or No Difference at All?, Festschrift Zweigert, 388 (1981).<br />

85. Goodhart, supra note 73, at 259.<br />

86. Id. at 263.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 642 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 643<br />

opposite positions, they are gradually moving closer together even in their<br />

methods and techniques."<br />

Furthermore, in England, the doctrine of stare decisis is not as widely accepted<br />

as it had been years earlier.m In 1966, the Lord Chancellor issued a Practice<br />

<strong>State</strong>ment recognizing the importance of certainty in the law but abandoning the<br />

rule that the House of Lords was strictly bound by its own previous decisions. 9 He<br />

declared:<br />

Their Lordships regard the use of precedent as an indispensable<br />

foundation upon which to decide what is the law and its application to<br />

individual cases. It provides at least some degree of certainty upon which<br />

individuals can rely in the conduct of their affairs as well as a basis for<br />

orderly development of legal rules.<br />

Their Lordships nevertheless recognize that too rigid adherence to<br />

precedent may lead to injustice in a particular case and also unduly restrict<br />

the proper development of the law. They propose, therefore, to modify<br />

their present practice and, while treating former decisions of this House as<br />

normally binding, to depart from a previous decision when it appears right<br />

to do so.<br />

In this connection they will bear in mind the danger of disturbing<br />

retrospectively the basis on which contracts, settlements of property and<br />

fiscal arrangements have been entered into and also the special need for<br />

certainty as to the criminal law.<br />

This announcement is not intended to affect the use of precedent<br />

elsewhere than in this House. ([1966] 1 WLF 1234). 0<br />

In response to the Lord Chancellor's Practice <strong>State</strong>ment, support increased in<br />

England for further restriction of the doctrine of stare decisis." Lord Denning<br />

continuously advocated that the Court of Appeal should also be free to depart from<br />

strictly following previous decisions. 92 He contended that if adhering to precedent<br />

too rigidly leads to injustice and restricts the development of the law in the House of<br />

Lords, it will do the same in the Court of Appeal. 93 However, Lord Denning's view<br />

was ultimately rejected by a unanimous House of Lords in Davis v. Johnson in<br />

1979. 9 '<br />

87. Id. at 271.<br />

88. Id. at 261.<br />

89. See id. at 261-62.<br />

90. Id.<br />

91. Goodhart, supra note 73, at 262.<br />

92. Id.<br />

93. Id.<br />

94. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 643 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

Mauro Cappelletti advocated a different position in the matter of the<br />

convergence of common and civil law. He maintained that not as much convergence<br />

had occurred as Zweigert and Kotz suggest and the precedential authority of civil<br />

law decisions do not compare to the common law doctrine of stare decisis. 9 " Major<br />

differences continue to exist between the two systems that lead to varied<br />

precedential authority of previous decisions. 96<br />

The first difference, according to Cappelletti, exists in the organization of<br />

higher courts in common and civil law systems. 9 While common law nations have a<br />

compact unitary system with a single highest court, civil law nations do not have a<br />

similar court structure. 98 Rather, civil law nations have a diffuse court system with<br />

numerous high courts. 99 France and Italy have three different court systems, one for<br />

ordinary civil and criminal matter, one for administrative matter, and a<br />

constitutional court.'" ° The Constitutional Court in Italy, La Corte Costituzionale,<br />

has the authority to resolve controversies on the constitutionality of laws and<br />

enactments issued by the <strong>State</strong> and the various regions, to resolve conflicts arising<br />

from allocation of powers, and to deal with accusations made against the President<br />

of the Republic."" The constitutional court in France, le Conseil Constitutionnel, has<br />

limited constitutional power, but has consultative powers as well as judicial authority<br />

over normative and abstract proceedings and electoral and referendum disputes.<br />

Germany has five different court systems, one each for ordinary civil and criminal,<br />

administrative, tax, labor and social matters. 1 3 Germany also has a constitutional<br />

court, the Bundesverfassungsgericht, whose sole task is judicial review.'" This<br />

diffuse organization leads to diffuse authority of high court decisions. 1 " 5<br />

A second difference that leads to varied precedential authority of previous<br />

decision is civil law's historical bias against judicial discretion."' 6 Traditionally, civil<br />

law nations distrust judges, and therefore, do not want to grant them too much<br />

power. ' 7 No writ of certiorari exists in civil law high courts that gives judges<br />

discretion to choose certain cases to hear."" Rather, civil law courts are courts of<br />

mandatory jurisdiction, must hear every case brought before them and decide<br />

thousands of cases each year." The result of the tremendous number of cases<br />

decided yearly by civil law high courts is that many of the cases are unpublished,<br />

unknown, and forgotten.' The minimal precedential authority of civil law high<br />

95. See Cappelletti, supra note 76, 387-88.<br />

96. See id. at 382-83.<br />

97. Id. at 383.<br />

98. Id. at 383-84.<br />

99. Id. at 383.<br />

100. Id.<br />

101. COST. Art. 134 (Italy), available at www.cortecostituzionale.it.<br />

102. Const. Title VII, Art. 56-63 (France), available at www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr.<br />

103. Cappelletti at 383.<br />

104. Bundesverfassungsgericht web site, http://www.bverfg.de/en/organization/task.html.<br />

105. Cappelletti, supra note 76, at 383.<br />

106. Id.<br />

107. Id. at 384.<br />

108. Id. at 385.<br />

109. Id. at 384.<br />

110. Id. at 386.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 644 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 645<br />

court decision does not compare to the precedential authority of common law high<br />

court decisions decided under the doctrine of stare decisis.",<br />

The third difference, cited by Cappelletti, is the use of sociological<br />

considerations regarding the judiciary in common and civil law Systems." 2 He<br />

contends that civil law career judges are trained to develop technical skills to<br />

mechanically apply the law."' 3 The judges are neither trained nor equipped to make<br />

policy-related decisions. 114<br />

4. Entry into the Third Millennium<br />

The era following the writings of Zweigert, Kotz and Cappelletti reveal an<br />

accelerated convergence of common and civil law due in part to developments in<br />

European Union and International law. In addition, the development of<br />

constitutional courts in Europe provides judges with the power to deliver decisions<br />

with great precedential weight." 5 Additionally, the decisions of ordinary and<br />

administrative courts in civil law nations have gained greater persuasive weight over<br />

the years."'<br />

The European Union is an example of convergence of common and civil law in<br />

practice. Judges and lawyers from both traditions are working together in the<br />

European Court of Justice. The development and discussion of European Principles<br />

of Contract <strong>Law</strong>, a European Civil Code, and a Global Commercial Code further<br />

facilitate harmonization of common and civil law. Additionally, international<br />

organizations, such as UNCITRAL, UNIDROIT, and the World Trade<br />

Organization, have contributed to the accelerated convergence by joining<br />

representatives from both common and civil law traditions to create international<br />

policies for the benefit of all contracting states. The harmonization of common and<br />

civil procedural law has made less progress compared to its substantive<br />

counterpart." 7 However, harmonization in this area is occurring and has been<br />

accelerated by the joint project between the American <strong>Law</strong> Institute and the<br />

UNIDROIT Working Group creating Principles and Rules of Transnational Civil<br />

Procedure.<br />

Technological revolution is also significantly impacting the convergence of<br />

common and civil law. The emergence of electronic reporting systems of texts and<br />

cases in areas such as the Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of<br />

Goods, enhances access to statutory material and case law. The development of<br />

111. Cappelletti, supra note 76, at 387.<br />

112. Id. at 383.<br />

113. Id. at387.<br />

114. Id.<br />

115. See id. at 392.<br />

116. See JOHN HENRY MERRYMAN & DAVID S. CLARK, COMPARATIVE LAW: WESTERN EUROPEAN<br />

& LATIN AMERICAN LEGAL SYSTEMS, 551-86 (1978).<br />

117. Joint American <strong>Law</strong> Institute/UNIDROIT Working Group on Principles and Rules of<br />

Transnational Civil Procedure, International Institute for the Unification of Private <strong>Law</strong> 2003, Study<br />

LXXVI - Doc. 10, 2, available at http://www.unidroit.org/english/publications/proceedings/2003/study/76/s-<br />

76-10-e.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 645 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

these reporting systems in other areas of international law will ultimately lead to<br />

greater convergence of legal systems.<br />

5. Experience of Constitutional Courts in Europe and Case <strong>Law</strong> in Civil <strong>Law</strong><br />

Systems<br />

The development of a centralized system of judicial review in civil law nations<br />

has accelerated the convergence of common and civil law. The experience of<br />

constitutional courts in Europe has led to greater precedential weight of decisions<br />

emanating from those constitutional courts, giving them a "stare-decisis like<br />

authority." ' ... While civil law nations have a centralized system of judicial review<br />

with power entrusted to a special constitutional court, common law nations have a<br />

decentralized system of judicial review with all courts given the power of judicial<br />

review." 9 Constitutional courts have developed in civil law nations like Austria,<br />

Germany, Italy, and Spain because ordinary and administrative courts are not<br />

prepared to participate in judicial review. 2<br />

Civil law differs from common law because judicial decisions are generally not a<br />

source of law and the doctrine of stare decisis does not formally exist. However,<br />

some civil law nations, including France and Mexico, both informally and formally<br />

recognize the persuasive effect of previous decisions in ordinary and administrative<br />

courts. France explicitly rejects the doctrine of stare decisis because the principle of<br />

separation of power prevents French courts from formally creating legal rules. 2 ' The<br />

role of French courts is to solve disputes brought before them, not to make law.' 22<br />

However, judicial precedents may be cited in court and often affect French courts'<br />

ultimate decisions because there is a natural tendency to follow precedent, despite<br />

Article 5 of the French Civil Code. 3 In Mexico's civil law tradition, the doctrine of<br />

stare decisis is likewise not formally recognized, but the Supreme Court and collegial<br />

circuit tribunals can establish a binding precedent by issuing five consecutive<br />

decisions, with no incompatible rulings in between, on a certain point of law. 4 This<br />

binding precedent, known as Jurisprudencia, is binding on the court that establishes<br />

it and all lower state and federal courts that lie within the court's geographic<br />

jurisdiction. 2 "<br />

However, not all civil law nations have recognized the persuasive weight of<br />

previous decisions even though in practice, attorneys look to reported cases in<br />

interpreting statutes and codes. The sources of Italian law are statutes, regulations,<br />

corporative norms, and usage. 6 The Italian Code makes no mention of judicial<br />

decisions as a source of law; thus, the Doctrine of stare decisis is in theory rejected. 7<br />

118. Cappelletti, supra note 76, at 392.<br />

119. Id. at 391.<br />

120. See id.<br />

121. MERRYMAN & CLARK, supra note 116, at 561.<br />

122. Id.<br />

123. Id. at 562; "Judges are forbidden to decide cases submitted to them by way of general and<br />

regulatory provisions." Civ., Preliminary Title, Art. 5 (Fr.)<br />

124. MERRYMAN & CLARK, supra note 116, at 574.<br />

125. Id. at 575.<br />

126. See THE ITALIAN CIVIL CODE AND COMPLEMENTARY LEGISLATION, Booklet 2, Chap. 1<br />

(Susanna Beltranmo ed. and trans., 2003).<br />

127. See id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 646 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 647<br />

Italian law officially emphasizes strict separation of power, which justifies restricting<br />

courts to mere interpretation and application of the law, not making the law.1 2<br />

6. Case <strong>Law</strong> Experience of the European Union: An Example of Civil and<br />

Common <strong>Law</strong> Convergence in Practice<br />

An example of the convergence of common and civil law in practice is the<br />

European Union. The European Court of Justice (ECJ) is the judicial branch of the<br />

European Union. The ECJ plays a significant role in European integration.' 2 9 Its<br />

formal role is to ensure that the interpretation and application of European Union<br />

treaties are within the proper bounds of the law. 3 ' Today, the ECJ consists of<br />

twenty-five judges, one selected from each member-state, and eight advocates<br />

general."' Thus, judges come from both common and civil law traditions because,<br />

while most of the member-states have a civil law tradition, England and Ireland are<br />

common law nations. Therefore, judges from different legal traditions must<br />

accommodate and work together in the European Court of Justice.<br />

There are two stages of procedure in the European Court of Justice, a written<br />

stage and an oral stage.' 32 The written stage of the proceeding is the most thorough<br />

and most important stage in the proceeding, which is consistent with civil law<br />

tradition.' 33 The oral stage of the proceeding is limited and short, in which the<br />

interested parties merely restate their positions already presented in their written<br />

submissions. The ECJ may even propose to cancel the oral proceeding if the<br />

parties agree.' 35 During the oral stage, the judges and the advocate-general ask the<br />

advocates questions to clarify and focus the issues that are specifically important to<br />

them.' 36 This practice is also consistent with civil law tradition. Additionally,<br />

consistent with civil law judicial decisions, no dissent or concurring opinions are<br />

permitted in the European Court of Justice.' 37 The deliberations of the Court are<br />

kept secret and the decision is made by consensus and given in a unanimous opinion<br />

of the Court.38<br />

The common law doctrine of stare decisis does not formally exist in the<br />

European Court of Justice's practice; therefore, the Court is not bound by its own<br />

precedent. 9 However, precedent has become increasingly important in the ECJ<br />

since the United Kingdom entered the European Community in 1973.1'4 Although<br />

precedent is not a formal source of ECJ law, the Court often specifically refers to<br />

128. Merryman & Clark, supra note 116,at 557.<br />

129. See DEREK BEACH, BETWEEN LAW & POLITICS: THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN THE<br />

EUROPEAN COURT OF JUSTICE & EU MEMBER STATES 17 (2001).<br />

130. See id. at 23.<br />

131. See id. at 24.<br />

132. See id. at 29-30.<br />

133. See id. at 29.<br />

134. See id. at 30.<br />

135. Beach, supra note 129, at 30.<br />

136. See id. at 30.<br />

137. See id. at 31.<br />

138. See id.<br />

139. See id. at 85.<br />

140. Id. at 85.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 647 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

previous decisions' 1 and advocates cite cases freely in written briefs and during the<br />

oral stage of the proceeding. Thus, the procedure and practice of the European<br />

Court of Justice is a practical example of the convergence of common and civil law<br />

necessary for a successful judicial system in the European Union.<br />

7. Other Perspectives: The Role of Precedent in Mexico<br />

While Goodhart believes that the application of the doctrine of stare decisis is<br />

the major difference in the common and civil law system, Zweigert and Kotz point<br />

out that because of the evolution of the two systems they may not be as divergent as<br />

once believed. The Mexican system is an additional example of the convergence<br />

occurring between civil and common law systems. By definition, Mexico is a civil<br />

law country, relying on codes and statutes to provide legal sources. However, it has<br />

adopted and adapted some of the practices of its northern neighbors. Through the<br />

process of convergence, the antithetical aspect of civil law, the doctrine of stare<br />

decisis, is being absorbed into Mexican legal culture.<br />

The structure of the Mexican legal system is similar to that of its civil law<br />

brethren. Historically, there has been a strict division of legislative and adjudicative<br />

functions of government.' 2 The Mexican Supreme Court has had the power to<br />

create precedent in circumstances of amparo" ' decisions since 1909, but the<br />

Constitution did not recognize this power until the 1950-1951 amendments." When<br />

the Constitution was further amended in 1968, the precedent-creating power was not<br />

specifically mentioned.<br />

However, it was taken as an assumption and extended to include Collegial<br />

Circuit Tribunal decisions. 4 ' Though there has never been consensus concerning the<br />

exact application and use of precedent, the 1951 amendments made the precedents a<br />

legitimate source of law. This explicit recognition is a unique feature in a civil law<br />

country and a large step toward convergence of civil and common law traditions.<br />

Though Mexico has adopted the unique blend of civil and common law, the law<br />

created by the courts does not hold the same status as judge made law does in<br />

common law countries. The Mexican Supreme Court has recognized that the<br />

application of jurisprudecia should never encroach into legislative functions. The<br />

jurisprudencia must only<br />

6<br />

be used to interpret, never create law.' As Merryman and<br />

Clark state, jurisprudencia is always to be considered an "auxiliary," never an<br />

"autonomous" source of law."' 7 Though the jurisprudencia may appear to be of<br />

similar weight and influence of that of the U.S. Supreme Court decisions, civil law<br />

traditions still constrain the application of the decisions to impact far less than the<br />

decisions of American courts. Mexican jurisprudencia has been effectively used to<br />

141. Beach, supra note 129, at 85.<br />

142. MERRYMAN & CLARK, supra note 116, at 572.<br />

143. The juicio de amparo, or amparo for short, is a writ of protection that secures individual rights<br />

protected in the Constitution. It allows individuals to protect their rights against the government in<br />

criminal, civil, administrative and labor disputes. Alexis James Gilman, Making Amends with the Mexican<br />

Constitutions: Reassessing the 1995 Judicial Reforms and Considering Prospects for Further Reform, 35<br />

GEO. WASH. INT'L. L. REV. 947, 951-52 (2003).<br />

144. MERRYMAN & CLARK, supra note 116, at 572.<br />

145. Id. at 571.<br />

146. Id.<br />

147. Id. at 572.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 648 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 649<br />

clarify ambiguities and fill in gaps, but it could not be used to create law as seen in<br />

American courts.<br />

Precedent plays a unique role in Mexico's civil law system. The Mexican model<br />

draws from the rich traditions of both civil and common law countries. Civil law<br />

countries do not follow the doctrine of stare decisis. Mexico has blended the<br />

doctrine of stare decisis into its civil law tradition. While not technically binding,<br />

higher court decisions based on similar facts and law carry very persuasive<br />

authority.' 4 ' These persuasive decisions are known as ejecutorias. If an ejecutoria is<br />

followed the requisite number of times and with the proper procedure, it can create<br />

precedent.' 49<br />

Cases decided by the Supreme Court and Federal Circuit Collegiate Courts<br />

have the ability to create jurisprudencia. A jurisprudencia is a "term of art used to<br />

refer to the event whereby five uninterrupted and consecutive judicial resolutions<br />

rendered by the Supreme Court of Justice, or by a Circuit Collegiate Tribunal,<br />

sharing the same legal holding, become obligatory to all lower courts, provided that<br />

said federal resolutions had been approved by eight of the eleven Justices<br />

(Ministros) when decided by the Supreme Court en banc, or by four Justices of the<br />

relevant panel when generated by a Supreme Court Chamber."' 50 If a case is decided<br />

by a Collegial Circuit Tribunal, the decision must be unanimously approved by all<br />

three magistrates. 51 As each ejecutoria is repeated in its progression toward<br />

jurisprudencia it gains persuasive authority on the lower courts.' 52 If an ejecutoria is<br />

interrupted in its progression toward becoming jurisprudecia, the process must begin<br />

anew. There must be five more consistent opinions for that point of law to become<br />

binding as jurisprudencia. Once a jurisprudencia is created, however, a decision that<br />

contradicts its holding can have the effect of repealing it.' 3 To overrule a<br />

jurisprudencia, the contradictory ruling must be supported by at least fourteen<br />

Ministros.<br />

Once a court is authorized with the power of creating jurisprudencia, that court<br />

is bound by its own internal decisions, but not decisions by other courts."'<br />

Jurisprudencia of the Supreme Court is binding on all lower courts. Jurisprudencias<br />

created by the Collegial Circuit Tribunals are binding on lower district courts.' 55<br />

Though the jurisprudencias created by higher courts are binding upon the<br />

subordinate judiciary, this binding effect does not extend past the court systems.<br />

Unlike common law systems where judicial decisions will influence, if not bind the<br />

executive or legislative functions, the jurisprudencias in Mexico do not reach past the<br />

judiciary." 6 For example, if the Mexican Supreme Court declared a legislative act to<br />

be unconstitutional, it is unlikely that the legislative branch would be inclined to<br />

conform its legislation with the judicial decision unless there was a policy reason for<br />

148. Jorge A. Vargas, Moral Damages Under the Civil <strong>Law</strong> of Mexico: Are These Damages Equivalent<br />

to U.S. Punitive Damages?, 35 U. MIAMI INTER-AM. L. REV. 183,241.<br />

149. Id.<br />

150. Id. at 242.<br />

151. MERRYMAN & CLARK, supra note 116, at 574.<br />

152. Vargas, supra note 148, at 243.<br />

153. MERRYMAN & CLARK, supra note 116, at 579.<br />

154. Id. at 575.<br />

155. Id.<br />

156. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 649 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

doing so." 7 When a Mexican court has declared a law unconstitutional and one of<br />

the other branches has failed to comply with this determination, a person aggrieved<br />

by this action has no choice but to file another amparo action.<br />

The 1995 reforms expanded the Supreme Court's authority. 158 These<br />

amendments granted the Supreme Court, when approved by a majority of eight<br />

judges, the power to create precedent in a single decision. This power was limited,<br />

however, to four types of cases:<br />

(1) a controversy between the executive and legislative branches; (2) a<br />

conflict between two authorities of a single state regarding the<br />

constitutionality of acts of general provisions; (3) a dispute between two<br />

authorities of the federal legislative district; or (4) controversies involving<br />

the federal government violating the general provisions of Mexican states<br />

of municipalities. 9<br />

Without the requisite vote and in all other types of cases, the Supreme Court's<br />

decision is binding only on the parties presently in litigation.'6<br />

B. Status of Selected Current Substantive Harmonization Projects<br />

The following is a comment on the Principles of European Contract <strong>Law</strong>, a<br />

European Civil Code, a Global Commercial Code, and the UNIDROIT Principles of<br />

International Commercial Contracts and how they facilitate common and civil law.<br />

1. Principles of European Contract <strong>Law</strong><br />

The discussion and development of the Principles of European Contract <strong>Law</strong> is<br />

an effort by the Lando Commission to harmonize the varying contract laws of<br />

European countries. 16 ' Harmonization of European commercial law is necessary<br />

because economic pressures exist in the European Union concerning the open<br />

market and facilitation of trade. Similar economic pressure and need for uniformity<br />

accelerated the establishment of the National Conference of Commissioners on<br />

Uniform <strong>State</strong> <strong>Law</strong>s when the first efforts were made in 1889 to unify individual<br />

state law in the United <strong>State</strong>s.' 62 The Conference of Commissioners on Uniform<br />

<strong>State</strong> <strong>Law</strong>s began its effort to develop uniform state laws to facilitate interstate<br />

commerce. 63 In response to major commercial problems in the United <strong>State</strong>s, the<br />

Conference decided in 1940 to create comprehensive legal solutions to those<br />

problems and began a project to produce the Uniform Commercial Code."' The<br />

157. Id. at 576.<br />

158. Gilman, supra note 143, at 958.<br />

159. Id. at 958.<br />

160. Id.<br />

161. See Andrea Pinna, Drafting a Civil Code for Europe: Aims & Methods 2 (2001), available at<br />

http://palissy.humana.univ-nantes.fr/msh/prog/ssn/SSN02.pdf.<br />

162. See Uniform <strong>Law</strong> Commissioners; The National Conference of Commissioners on Uniform <strong>State</strong><br />

<strong>Law</strong>s available at http://www.nccusl.org (the Conference's first meeting was held in 1892).<br />

163. See id.<br />

164. See Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 650 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 651<br />

UCC took ten years to complete; it took another fourteen years before every state in<br />

the United <strong>State</strong>s, with the exception of Louisiana, enacted it with or without<br />

modification. 9<br />

The purpose of developing the Principles of European Contracts is to provide a<br />

restatement of the law of contracts, similar to the Restatements in the United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

and to enact the Principles and give them the force of law.'6 The Principles are not<br />

the codification of existing contract law, but rather are a new, complete set of rules<br />

to govern all aspects of contracts. 167 The drafters attempt to modernize existing<br />

European contract law with solutions that may exist in some European <strong>State</strong>s, but<br />

tend to be a desirable development of European contract law."<br />

2. European Civil Code<br />

Since 1997, the idea of a European Civil Code has been actively discussed by<br />

Europeans. 9 The discussion surrounding the development of a European Civil<br />

Code focuses on unification and harmonization of all aspects of European private<br />

law, which would in turn lead to unification and harmonization of common and civil<br />

law systems. In 1997, the symposium Towards a European Civil Code occurred in<br />

Den Haag.' 70 The Minister of Justice marked the opening of the symposium with a<br />

speech advocating the need for a European Civil Code' According to the Minister,<br />

overall harmonization of private law in Europe is both possible and necessary to<br />

strengthen Europe's internal market .' However, he recognized that a European<br />

Civil Code must bridge the gap between different legal traditions in Europe,<br />

including the common and civil law.17<br />

Unification seems possible and most urgent in the law of obligations and<br />

movable property.' 74 On the other hand, unified rules relating to immovables, family<br />

law, and succession law seem less realistic and less urgent.' The purpose of<br />

developing a Civil Code for Europe is similar to the purpose for developing<br />

European Principles of Contract <strong>Law</strong>, but on a broader scale. The goal is to provide<br />

a Restatement of the various civil laws throughout Europe and eventually enact the<br />

Civil Code, giving it the force of law.' 76 A reason asserted for codification of<br />

European Private <strong>Law</strong> is to reduce high transaction costs and enhance legal security<br />

165. See id. (Louisiana enacted various articles of the Code individually. It completed actual adoption<br />

of the Code in 1990, but only implemented Revised Article 9 in 2001).<br />

166. Pinna, supra note 161, at 4.<br />

167. ld. at 2.<br />

168. MERRYMAN & CLARK, supra note 116, at 2-3.<br />

169. See Ulrich Drobnig, Unified Private <strong>Law</strong> for the European Internal Market, 106 Dick. L. Rev.<br />

101,107 (2001).<br />

170. Ewoud Houdinus, Towards a European Civil Code, in TOWARDS A EUROPEAN CIVIL CODE 3, 3-<br />

20 (Arthur Hartkamp et al. eds., 2004).<br />

171. See id.<br />

172. Id.<br />

173. Id.<br />

174. Drobnig, supra note 169, at 107.<br />

175. Id.<br />

176. Pinna, supra note 161, at 4.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 651 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

within Europe. 77 Codification would reduce transaction costs because civil laws in<br />

each member state differ and the uncertainty surrounding each member state's<br />

particular law hinders cross-boarder exchange in the European Union. 8<br />

Furthermore, unifying European civil law will increase the effectiveness of a single<br />

European market. 7 "<br />

However, not all Europeans are convinced that a European Code is desirable. 8 °<br />

Some skeptics fear the cultural identity of individual European <strong>State</strong>s will be<br />

endangered if its own civil law is supplemented and absorbed by European law. 8 '<br />

Another source of opposition deals with the potential difficulties of working within<br />

two legal cultures.'8 Many argue that common law nations will reject the idea of a<br />

Code based on their tradition of predominance of case law. However, common law<br />

nations in the European Community, including England and Ireland, are<br />

increasingly accepting the written law, while the influence of case law in civil law<br />

nations is increasing. 83 Furthermore, the two opposing legal systems work together<br />

in the application of the Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of<br />

Goods,' which shows that they are able to work together in the application of a<br />

European Civil Code as well.<br />

While the majority of academics in Europe agree that the current acquis in that<br />

area is inconsistent and fragmented and that this is the inevitable effect of the<br />

"piecemeal approach" towards harmonization in the civil law area, the opinions<br />

regarding the Common Frame of Reference, its contents and its role-as well as the<br />

possibility of creating some kind of codified instrument based on it at a later stagevary<br />

greatly. Professor Pierre Legrand directly opposes the idea of a European Civil<br />

Code and represents the group of academics in Europe who believe that Europe<br />

should be the way it is-a continent that consists of multiple legal orders."' Others,<br />

like Professor Jan Smits are against the idea for the creation of a European Civil<br />

Code in a wrong way and for the wrong reasons. Professor Smits opposes the idea of<br />

a binding European Civil Code forced from above-the institutions of the Union. 6<br />

But he embraces the idea of the creation of an optional code, a "26 h regime," which<br />

the contracting parties will be free to choose if they so desired. He takes a very<br />

economic and competitive view-that the best solution for the parties should emerge<br />

through free competition of the legal orders in the Union. This will benefit both the<br />

parties and the national legal systems. The parties will benefit from the fact that<br />

they are able to choose freely the best option for themselves. The national legal<br />

systems will be forced to improve their regimes in order to make their environment<br />

more attractive for businesses and thus will become more competitive and constantly<br />

self-improve. In other words, "[t]hose for whom the law exists should decide which<br />

177. Id. at 4-6.<br />

178. See id. at 5.<br />

179. Id.<br />

180. See Drobnig, supra note 169, at 108.<br />

181. Id.<br />

182. Pinna, supra note 161, at 6.<br />

183. Id. at 6-7.<br />

184. Id. at 7.<br />

185. Pierre Legrand, Against a European Civil Code, 60 MOD. L. REv. 44 (1997).<br />

186. Jan M. Smits, European Private <strong>Law</strong>: A Plea for a Spontaneous Legal Order 19-20 (Maastricht<br />

Faculty of <strong>Law</strong> Working Paper 2006/3, 2006), available at<br />

http://www.unimaas.nl/default.asp?template=werkveld.htm&id=F60BL5POOMJ0466V63M6&taal=nl.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 652 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 653<br />

rules serve their interests best.""'" Professor Smits also doubts the ability of the<br />

Common Frame of Reference to solve the problems with the current acquis and to<br />

improve the future acquis. Instead, his proposal centers around the idea of<br />

combining all relevant directives in the area into a single "codified" directive.<br />

Professor Norbert Reich expresses pessimistic views on the possible creation of<br />

a European Civil Code but for other reasons. According to him, the competence of<br />

the Community in the area of contract law is limited to certain areas where contract<br />

law may have a specific impact on other Community policies like internal market,<br />

competition, consumer protection, and social policy.' 88 Thus, no horizontal<br />

competence in contract law exists for the European Community. 8 9 However, he<br />

proposes an idea like that expressed by Professor Smits, that competition of legal<br />

orders and not harmonization might actually be a solution to the problems raised in<br />

the Commission's Communication of 2001.1"°<br />

The group of optimists on this initiative consists mainly of the academics<br />

involved in the research teams throughout Europe. Their belief is that the twentyfive<br />

different legal orders present an obstacle to cross-border transactions mainly<br />

through the fact that it increases the costs of transactions and because the parties are<br />

unfamiliar with the other legal system. Thus, the twenty-five different legal systems<br />

can hinder the functioning of the internal market. According to this group of<br />

academics, creating a codified instrument that will employ common terms, principles,<br />

and definitions will be able to solve those problems. However, internally, this group<br />

is divided into small groups. While some believe that a mandatory code is needed<br />

for the problems to be solved,' 8 ' others like Professor Martijn Hesselink, think that<br />

while the drafting of European Civil Code involves many choices that are essentially<br />

political, the technocratic approach adopted by the Commission in its Action Plan of<br />

2003 effectively excludes most stakeholders from expressing their views.' 9 He<br />

suggests that the Commission should try to re-politicize the process and thus increase<br />

the democratic basis of the European Civil Code and consequently its legitimacy.' 9<br />

Professor Christian von Bar, the Chairman of the Study Group on a European<br />

Civil Code, expressed the joint view of the group by stating that<br />

the partial and fragmentary nature of EU competence in the field of<br />

private law encourages a segmental approach to harmonization which<br />

disturbs the coherence of the interlocking concepts and principles in the<br />

national jurisdictions. A general and transparent empowerment of the EU<br />

in this field is needed to facilitate general measures on the basis of a wider<br />

187. Id. at 20.<br />

188. Norbert Reich, Some Critical Comments on the Commission Communication of 11.07.2001,<br />

COM(2001) 398 final "On European Contract <strong>Law</strong>," at 2 (Sept. 2001), available at<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/consumers/policy/development/contract-aw/comments/5.1 4.pdf.<br />

189. Id. at 2.<br />

190. Id. at 4.<br />

191. See, e.g., UGO MATrI, Hard Code Now! A Critique and a Plea for Responsibility in the<br />

European Debate over Codification, in THE EUROPEAN CODIFICATION PROCESS: CUT AND PASTE, 107,<br />

107 (2003).<br />

192. Martijn W. Hesselink, The Politics of a European Civil Code, 10 EUR. L. J. 675, 675 (2004),<br />

available at http://www.europeanlawjournal.com/contents-detail.asp?JournallD=43.<br />

193. Id. at 675-76.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 653 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

and more systematic vision which do not cut across or undermine the<br />

existing sophisticated apparatus of private law in the Member <strong>State</strong>s. ' 9<br />

3. UNIDROIT Principles 2004: A Further Step Toward a Global Contract<br />

<strong>Law</strong><br />

The Principles of International Commercial Contracts created by the<br />

International organization UNIDROIT (UNIDROIT Principles) address contracts<br />

between merchants in an international context. The UNIDROIT Principles attempt<br />

to present rules common to most existing legal systems, but also select the most<br />

adaptable solutions to the requirements of international trade. 9 The majority rule is<br />

not necessarily chosen; rather, the Principles reflect the most persuasive rule that is<br />

best suited for cross-border transactions. 9 6 In drafting the UNIDROIT Principles,<br />

the group considered national codifications or compilations of law, such as the<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s Uniform Commercial Code, the Restatement (2nd) of the <strong>Law</strong> of<br />

Contracts, and other similar efforts.' 97 The 1980 United Nations Convention on<br />

Contracts for the International Sale of Goods was also referred to in drafting the<br />

UNIDROIT Principles. 99 The UNIDROIT principles are drafted in the style of the<br />

European Codes, rather than the elaborate style of common law statutes. 9 9 The<br />

UNIDROIT Principles also avoid using terminology peculiar to any specific legal<br />

system. °° The scope of the UNIDROIT Principles is limited to International<br />

Contracts because great differences continue to exist between nations and regions<br />

regarding the contract law applicable to their economic and political structure."'<br />

The UNIDROIT Principles are used in practice as a model for legislators, a<br />

guide for drafting international contracts, a choice by parties to govern their<br />

contract, and applications in judicial proceedings. 2 Other nations have referred to<br />

the UNIDROIT Principles in reports or interpretive rules and some have even used<br />

the Principles as a model to reform domestic law. 2 3 In addition, if international<br />

parties use the terminology present in the UNIDROIT Principles, they will have<br />

neutral terminology with a uniform definition to control their contract." °<br />

Furthermore, if international parties agree that UNIDROIT Principles govern their<br />

contract, a choice between competing domestic laws to govern the contract will be<br />

unnecessary."' Finally, the UNIDROIT principles are often cited in arbitration<br />

proceedings and in domestic courts. 2 "<br />

194. Christian von Bar, The Contribution of the Study Group on a European Civil Code to the<br />

European Convention (Apr. 4, 2004), available at http://www.sgecc.net (last visited Apr. 17, 2007).<br />

195. Michael Joachim Bonell, The Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts:<br />

Towards a New Lex Mercatoria?, 2 INT'L Bus. L.J. 145,147 (1997).<br />

196. Id.<br />

197. Id.<br />

198. Id. at 148.<br />

199. Id. at 149.<br />

200. Id. at 150.<br />

201. Bonell, supra note 195, at 150-51.<br />

202. Id. at 152-55.<br />

203. Id. at 152-53.<br />

204. Id. at 153.<br />

205. Id. at 154.<br />

206. Id. at 155.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 654 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 655<br />

4. Global Commercial Code<br />

In 1970 the Secretariat of UNIDROIT submitted a note to the newly<br />

established United Nations Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong> (UNCITRAL)<br />

in justification of a code of international trade law." 7 The proposed code was<br />

composed of two parts. Part one would deal with the law of obligations generally.<br />

Part two would relate to specific kinds of commercial transactions. 2 "' The<br />

UNIDROIT note did not address which type of instrument (i.e., convention, model<br />

law, soft law, etc.) should be used by the proposed code. The Progressive<br />

Codification was not given priority due to limited resources and skepticism as to its<br />

feasibility."" However, support remains for the idea that globalization of the world<br />

entails a need for uniform rules.<br />

In 2000, Gerold Hermann, long time Secretary of UNCITRAL, proposed the<br />

idea of a global commercial code to compile special rules governing the most<br />

important commercial transactions . 2 " He proposed something different from the<br />

original UNIDROIT proposal."' The code should be composed of the existing rules<br />

of international conventions and model rules. He conceived of it as an open-ended<br />

instrument intended "to weld together into a logical and integrated work" existing<br />

and future uniform laws in the field of international trade law. In Hermann's<br />

proposed code there could also be a provision permitting parties to an international<br />

contract to choose the UNIDROIT Principles as the law applicable to their contract.<br />

Alternatively the code could provide that the UNIDROIT Principles are applicable<br />

unless parties explicitly exclude them by choosing another applicable law or<br />

otherwise. 2 3 However, Herrmann envisioned that the code would become a model<br />

law adopted by <strong>State</strong>s. He cited the adoption of the U.C.C. by the states in the<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s as support for his idea that the code could "advance international<br />

codification .. .by serving as an example of a successful unification of the laws of<br />

many jurisdictions., 21 4<br />

Michael Joachim Bonell followed up on this idea of a Code to apply to crossborder<br />

transactions between business people and between individuals. Leaving open<br />

the question of its applicability to so-called consumer contracts, he suggests that the<br />

Global Commercial Code should avoid interfering with existing or future domestic<br />

rules for the protection of consumers."' It should not be a strict commercial code<br />

conceived as a special set of rules conceived for merchants distinct from the general<br />

civil code because no such civil code exists at the international level and also because<br />

207. See Progressive Codification of the <strong>Law</strong> of International Trade: Note by the Secretariat of the<br />

International Institute for the Unification of Private <strong>Law</strong> (UNIDROIT), [1968-70] 1 U.N. COMM'N ON INT'L<br />

TRADE L. Y.B. 285-86, U.N. Doc. A/CN.9/L.19.<br />

208. Michael Joachim Bonell, Do We Need a Global Commercial Code?, 106 DICK.L. REV. 87, 87<br />

(2001).<br />

209. Id.<br />

210. Gerold Hermann, The Role of UNCITRAL, in FOUNDATIONS AND PERSPECTIVES OF<br />

INTERNATIONAL TRADE LAW 28,35 (Ian Fletcher et al. eds., 2001).<br />

206. Bonell, supra note 208, at 88.<br />

212. Id.<br />

213. Id. at 91, 98.<br />

214. Id. at 89 n.9.<br />

215. Id. at 91.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 655 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

of the difficulties of distinguishing between "civil" and commercial parties and<br />

216<br />

transactions. Unlike Hermann, he felt that the existing instruments would have to<br />

be coordinated, rather than just transplanted into the Code, and should include the<br />

general contract law. 2 7 He agreed that the Global Commercial Code should be<br />

model law like the UCC but should be different than the UCC in that its scope<br />

should be limited to cross-border<br />

2 8<br />

transactions. This Global Code would be binding<br />

among nations that adopted it. He stressed that it should not be a comprehensive<br />

code that purports to provide answers to all legal disputes. 2 19 Additionally, he<br />

advised that the Global Commercial Code should not be mandatory and nations<br />

should not be prevented from modifying it. 22 Nations should be free to adopt it as<br />

proposed or modify it to account for the varying legal traditions and already adopted<br />

regional or universal laws dealing with identical areas. Something such as the<br />

UNIDROIT Principles of International Contracts 2004 (UPICC) would remain as<br />

soft law separate from the Global Code. These features would prevent such a Code<br />

from being overly ambitious.<br />

Ole Lando supports Bonell's ideas that the existing instruments will need to<br />

incorporate the general law of contracts in order to achieve the uniformity that is the<br />

underlying goal of the Code. 222 However, Lando seems to envision a less flexible<br />

version of the code and insists that if uniformity is to be achieved it would be<br />

necessary to make existing rules like the UNIDROIT Principles part of the Code<br />

and binding on the courts. 223 Lando suggests in detail the scope, substance and<br />

content, interpretation, mandatory rules, and other specific topics of the Code. 22 He<br />

argued that the Code should be limited to private law and analyzed the way the<br />

international law should interact with the laws of different countries.22 He proposes<br />

that some of the rules of the CISG be adopted along with rules now contained in<br />

UNIDROIT Principles of International Contracts 2004 (UPICC) and the Principles<br />

of European Contract <strong>Law</strong> (PECL) to become part of the Code. 226<br />

5. Other International Regimes' Impact on Convergence: UNCITRAL and<br />

the World Trade Organization<br />

The United Nations Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong> (UNCITRAL) is<br />

a body of member-states representing various regions which was established in 1966<br />

to further the harmonization and unification of the law of international trade. 227<br />

216. Id. at 90-91<br />

217. Bonell, supra note 208, at 92, 95.<br />

218. Id. at 94.<br />

219. Id. at 92-93.<br />

220. Id. at 93.<br />

221. See generally Michael Joachim Bonell, A Further Step Towards Global Contract <strong>Law</strong>: From<br />

UNIDROIT Principles 1994 to UNIDROIT Principles 2001, 37 UCC L.J. 49 (2004).<br />

222. See generally Ole Lando, A Vision of A Future World of Contract <strong>Law</strong> - Impact of European and<br />

UNIDROIT Contract Principles, 37 UCC L.J. 3 (2004).<br />

223. Id. at 9.<br />

224. Id. at 10-46.<br />

225. Id. at 11.<br />

226. Id. at 10-46.<br />

227. United Nations Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong> (UNCITRAL), FAQ - Origin,<br />

Mandate and Composition of UNCITRAL, http://www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/about/origin-faq.html.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 656 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 657<br />

Since its creation, UNCITRAL has established conventions, model laws, and other<br />

instruments to modernize laws. 22 These instruments are utilized by private parties in<br />

international trade transactions. 22 UNCITRAL creates solutions acceptable in<br />

different legal systems, including common and civil law systems. 3 ' One of the five<br />

regional groups within UNC1TRAL is "Western European and Other <strong>State</strong>s," which<br />

includes both common and civil law nations such as the United <strong>State</strong>s, the United<br />

211<br />

Kingdom, France, Italy, Spain, and Germany. Once a text is adopted by<br />

UNCITRAL consensus, the choice of whether a <strong>State</strong> will officially adopt it is made<br />

by lawmakers of the individual <strong>State</strong>s. 232<br />

An example of a text adopted by UNCITRAL that has been widely accepted<br />

and led to harmonization of opposing legal systems is the CISG, adopted in 1980.<br />

The CISG focuses on the development and unification of international trade. The<br />

CISG adopts uniform rules which govern contracts for the international sale of<br />

goods.<br />

Another international organization which facilitates convergence of common<br />

and civil law systems is the World Trade Organization (WTO). The WTO is an<br />

international organization established in 1995 that develops global rules of trade<br />

between nations. 233 The WTO has 150 members, coming from all legal systems,<br />

including common and civil law, which account for over 97% of world trade. 234<br />

These members must work together towards the primary objectives of the<br />

organization-helping trade flow smoothly, freely, fairly, and predictably. 235 Major<br />

functions of the WTO are to administer WTO trade agreements, provide a forum for<br />

trade negotiations, handle trade disputes, monitor national trade policies, provide<br />

technical assistance and training for developing countries, and cooperate with other<br />

international organizations. 3 ' These activities require cooperation of all members<br />

and facilitate the convergence of legal systems.<br />

C. Principles and Rules of Transnational Civil Procedure - An ALl and<br />

UNIDROIT Cooperative Harmonization Project "<br />

While the harmonization of substantive law has made great progress,<br />

harmonization of procedural law has been less successful. 237 While differences in<br />

common and civil law procedure may seem great, Professor Vincenzo Varano<br />

contends that harmonization is occurring and the procedural models are less at odds<br />

228. Id.<br />

229. Id.<br />

230. Id.<br />

231. Id.<br />

232. Id.<br />

233. World Trade Organization (WTO), http://www.wto.org/english/thewtoe/whatise.htm.<br />

234. Id.<br />

235. Id.<br />

236. Id.<br />

237. G. C. Hazard et al.. Draft Principles of Transnational Civil Procedure with Comments and Draft<br />

Rules of Transnational Civil Procedure with Comments 2 (Int'l Inst. For the Unification of Private <strong>Law</strong> -<br />

Joint American <strong>Law</strong> Institute/UNIDROIT Working Group on Principles and Rules of Transnational Civil<br />

Procedure, UNIDROIT Study LXXVI - Doc. 10, 2003), available at<br />

http://www.unidroit.org/english/publications.proceedings/2003/study/76/s-76-10-e.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 657 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

than they were made out to be in the past. 238 Both systems attribute the same<br />

purpose to civil procedure, which is to reach the efficient and just resolution of<br />

private disputes. 239 Although differences still exist between the two models, these<br />

differences, according to Varano, no longer have the importance they once had. 2 40<br />

The major difference between the two systems is based on the central feature of<br />

common law procedure: the jury. 2 ' The jury has produced features of the common<br />

law model of procedure that are distinct from the civil law approach, such as the<br />

importance of the oral stage of the proceeding, the sharp separation between the<br />

pre-trial state and the trial state, the passive role of the judge, and the detailed rules<br />

of evidence. 42 However, Varano contends that the jury's importance in common law<br />

procedure has been diminishing. 24'3 The jury has disappeared in the English system<br />

and the written elements of procedure have acquired a greater importance in the<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s procedural system. 244 Additionally, recent reforms in common law<br />

nations, such as England, Australia, and the United <strong>State</strong>s, grant the judge greater<br />

directional and management power, which decreases the adversarial nature of the<br />

proceeding. 245<br />

Procedural models vary not only between common law and civil law systems<br />

246<br />

but also among civil law nations. Some nations rely heavily on the written<br />

elements of procedure, while others emphasize the oral element. 2 47 Likewise, some<br />

civil law models are more inquisitorial while others are heavily influenced by the<br />

adversarial model. 2 4 Thus, differences not only exist between common and civil law<br />

systems, but also exist among the civil law procedural systems. 49<br />

Despite the harmonization of common and civil law procedural systems that<br />

Varano contends has taken place, differences continue to exist which cause problems<br />

when legal conflicts cross these procedural boundaries. A joint project by the<br />

American <strong>Law</strong> Institute and UNIDROIT has produced the Principles and Rules of<br />

Transnational Civil Procedure which attempts to harmonize these procedural<br />

differences. The Project emerged due to the negative consequences, such as the costs<br />

and distress, of working within various procedural systems. 20 These negative<br />

consequences can be mitigated by reducing the procedural differences so the same<br />

procedural rules apply wherever the conflict may be adjudicated. 251 The Principles<br />

and Rules provide a system that nations can adopt and employ when faced with<br />

238. Vincenzo Varano, Some Reflections on Procedure, Comparative <strong>Law</strong>, and the Common Core<br />

Approach, 3 GLOBAL JURIST TopIcs, No. 2, at 1-2, available at<br />

http://www.bepress.com/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1101&context=gj.<br />

239. Id. at 2.<br />

240. Id.<br />

241. Id.<br />

242. Id.<br />

243. Id.<br />

244. Varano, supra note 238, at 1-2.<br />

245. Id.<br />

246. See id.<br />

247. Id.<br />

248. Id.<br />

249. Id.<br />

250. ALI/UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES OF TRANSNATIONAL CIVIL PROCEDURE, AMERICAN LAW<br />

INSTITUTE (2006).<br />

251. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 658 2006-2007


2007 DEVELOPING GLOBAL TRANSNATIONAL HARMONIZATION PROCEDURES 659<br />

adjudication of international commercial disputes." The objective of these<br />

Principles and Rules is to offer a fair procedure to all parties and to reduce the<br />

uncertainty and anxiety resulting from litigation in unfamiliar surroundings. 253<br />

The Principles and Rules attempt to combine the best elements of the common<br />

law adversarial procedure with the best elements of the civil law judge-centered<br />

inquisitorial system. 25 ' The project recognizes numerous fundamental similarities as<br />

well as differences in the two procedural systems and tries to harmonize these<br />

aspects into a single set of Principles and Rules. An example of an issue addressed<br />

by the Principles and Rules is the rules for the formulation of claims. 256 The<br />

Principles and Rules require details with particulars regarding the basis of the claim;<br />

the particulars must also reveal a set of facts that would entitle the claimant to a<br />

favorable judgment. 27 The Principles and Rules regarding the exchange of evidence<br />

requires disclosure of sources of specific proof supporting the allegations set forth in<br />

the pleadings, such as relevant documents, expert reports, and summaries of<br />

expected witness testimony before the plenary hearing. 2 9 Therefore, the parties<br />

must have sufficient evidence to support their claims and be prepared to reveal all<br />

their evidence to the opponents without the opponents having to demand particular<br />

information. 2 9 Additionally, the rules provide a limited right to document discovery<br />

and deposition. 26 0 The Principles and Rules also address the procedure at the<br />

plenary hearing, second-instance review, and finality of decisions. 26 '<br />

D. Impact of Electronic International Reporting Systems on Convergence<br />

The worldwide revolution in communication technology has injected a new<br />

potential and momentum for substantial progress in planned and spontaneous<br />

harmonization of legal systems. The successful emergence of transnational<br />

electronic reporting systems facilitates harmonization of common and civil law<br />

systems. Enhanced capacity to communicate across borders and among different<br />

legal systems and cultures fosters achievement of desirable policy goals in public and<br />

private law. It also leads to greater efficiency and lowered costs in the exchange of<br />

information, documents, and ideas, and lower transaction costs for the commercial<br />

world. In some instances it provides information that otherwise would not be<br />

available to areas of the world that cannot afford to maintain voluminous hard copy<br />

libraries.<br />

Transnational electronic reporting systems facilitate universal access to legal<br />

systems. The data for identification of similarities and differences between legal<br />

systems is instantly available across distant borders and cultures for discussion and<br />

252. Id. at 3.<br />

253. Id. at 8.<br />

254. Id. at 7.<br />

255. See id. at 4.<br />

256. ALI/UNIDROIT, supra note 250, at 5.<br />

257. Id. at 5-6.<br />

258. Id. at 6.<br />

259. See id. at 6.<br />

260. Id. at 6.<br />

261. Id. at 7.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 659 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:625<br />

analysis, and it facilitates development of the consensus which is indispensable to<br />

achievement of successful harmonization.<br />

Ever-improving sophisticated electronic reporting is already available for the<br />

Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods. Existing reporting<br />

systems include the Pace <strong>Law</strong> School CISG Database 255 , UNILEX 256 , and<br />

UNCITRAL CLOUT (Case law on UNCITRAL Texts) 257 . These linked<br />

transnational electronic reporting systems provide updated legislative text,<br />

legislative history, case law, and access to the voluminous CISG literature. These<br />

pioneering systems can serve as a prototype for worldwide electronic reporting<br />

systems covering other areas of harmonized transnational law as they develop to<br />

meet the needs of an increasingly globalized world.<br />

255. See Pace <strong>Law</strong> School, The Autonomous Network of CISG Websites,<br />

www.cisg.law.pace.edu/network.html. This database contains a list of The Autonomous Network of CISG<br />

Websites from twenty-five countries, twenty-three of which can be viewed by hypertext links.<br />

256. See UNILEX, UNILEX on CISG and Unidroit Principles, www.unilex.info/dynasite.cfm.<br />

257. See United Nations Comm'n on Int'l Trade L. (UNCITRAL), Case <strong>Law</strong> on UNCITRAL Texts.<br />

www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/caselaw.html.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 660 2006-2007


Canadian Preference <strong>Law</strong> Reform<br />

ANTHONY DUGGAN' AND THOMAS G.W. TELFER'<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. In tro d u ctio n ......................................................................................................... 66 1<br />

II. The Evolution of Preference <strong>Law</strong> and Policy .................................................. 662<br />

A . The D ebtor Deterrence Rationale .............................................................. 662<br />

B. The Creditor D eterrence Rationale ............................................................ 664<br />

C. The Equal Sharing Rationale ..................................................................... 665<br />

D . Finality of Transactions .............................................................................. 667<br />

E. Facilitating the Provision of Credit to Financially Distressed Debtors ..667<br />

F. The Trade-O ffs ............................................................................................ 668<br />

III. C urrent C anadian <strong>Law</strong> ....................................................................................... 670<br />

A . In trod uction ................................................................................................. 670<br />

B . Pressure and D iligence ................................................................................ 674<br />

C . A ssessm ent ................................................................................................... 676<br />

IV . L aw R eform Initiatives ...................................................................................... 679<br />

V . C o n clusion ........................................................................................................... 684<br />

I. INTRODUCTION<br />

The preference provisions in the Canadian Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act'<br />

(BIA) have been virtually unchanged since the legislation was enacted in 1919,2 and<br />

many of their features derive from the nineteenth century and earlier English law.<br />

There have been various reform proposals over the years, but until now they have<br />

come to nothing. Most recently, in 2003 a Senate Committee recommended<br />

t Faculty of <strong>Law</strong>, University of Toronto.<br />

f Faculty of <strong>Law</strong>, University of Western Ontario.<br />

1. Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act, R.S.C., ch. B-3, §§95-6 (1985).<br />

2. There was an amendment the following year to exclude the doctrine of pressure. AN ACT TO<br />

AMEND THE BANKRUPTCY ACT, 10-11 George V (1920), 123. See also Part 111(b), infra.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 661 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:661<br />

amendments "to ensure consistent and simplified rules for challenging fraudulent<br />

preferences," but without explaining what was wrong with the current laws and how<br />

they should be changed? Recently enacted amendments aim to put the Senate<br />

Committee's recommendation into effect, but there is still no clear sense of the<br />

underlying objective' In any event, there are drafting problems, which will be<br />

explained later, and these will have to be fixed if the amendments are to have any<br />

impact at all. The drafting problems were at least in part a function of the failure to<br />

address policy objectives.<br />

This paper argues that: (1) the current Canadian preference provisions are<br />

deficient because: (a) they lack a clear policy foundation, (b) judicial glosses on the<br />

statutory text mean that the statute itself is an incomplete statement of the law; and<br />

(c) the amount of discretion the provisions give the courts results in inconsistent and<br />

unpredictable case outcomes; (2) these problems should be fixed, but meaningful<br />

reform is impossible unless we first decide what we want the preference laws to<br />

achieve;' and (3) Canada's lawmakers should address the policy choices before<br />

proceeding further with the current reform initiative.<br />

Part II surveys the evolution of preference law in common law countries and<br />

the competing policy objectives. Part III provides an overview of the current<br />

Canadian provisions and critically analyzes them with reference to the policy<br />

objectives identified in Part II. Part IV describes the most recent reform initiative<br />

and critically analyzes it with reference to the policy objectives identified in Part II.<br />

Part V concludes.<br />

II.<br />

THE EVOLUTION OF PREFERENCE LAW AND POLICY<br />

A. The Debtor Deterrence Rationale<br />

Broadly speaking, a preference is a payment of money or a transfer of property<br />

made by a debtor to a creditor on the eve of the debtor's bankruptcy, representing<br />

more than the amount the creditor would recover in the debtor's bankruptcy<br />

distribution. Early preference law developed through case authority. In The Case of<br />

Bankrupts (Smith v. Mills), Lord Coke stated the rationale for the avoidance of<br />

preferences in terms of the need to preserve the principle of equal distribution<br />

underlying the bankruptcy laws: "there ought to be an equal distribution ...... [for]<br />

if, after the debtor becomes a bankrupt, he may prefer [a creditor] and<br />

defeat and defraud many other poor men of their true debts, it would be unequal<br />

3. Standing S. Comm. on Banking, Trade and Com., 37th Parl., Debtors and Creditors Sharing the<br />

Burden: A Review of the Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act and the Companies' Creditors Arrangement Act<br />

at 123 (2d. Sess. 2003) [hereinafter Senate Committee Report].<br />

4. An Act To Establish the Wage Earner Protection Program Act, to Amend the Bankruptcy and<br />

Insolvency Act and the Companies' Creditors Arrangement Act and to Make Consequential Amendments<br />

to other Acts, 28 C. Gaz. 5, at 203 (Nov. 25, 2005) [hereinafter BIA Amending Act of 2005]. Proclamation<br />

of the BIA Amending Act 2005 has been postponed for at least six months to allow time for further<br />

deliberation.<br />

5. Commenting on the provincial preference legislation, Dunlop makes a similar point. "The first step<br />

is to decide what attitude the law should take to fraudulent preferences and then construct a statute which<br />

clearly and simply represents that policy. Patchwork amendment is not enough." C.R.B. Dunlop,<br />

Fraudulent Conveyances and Preferences: A Feasibility Study 10 (Uniform <strong>Law</strong> Conference of Canada<br />

2004), available at http://www.ulcc.ca/en/poam2/FraudulentPreferencesEn.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 662 2006-2007


2007<br />

CANADIAN PREFERENCE LAW REFORM<br />

and unconscionable, and a great defect in the law.", 6 Lord Mansfield expressed a<br />

similar view in Alderson v. Temple. According to Dickson J. in Hudson v.<br />

Benallack, this is still the policy of Canadian preference law:<br />

The object of the bankruptcy law is to ensure the division of the property<br />

of the debtor rateably among all his creditors in the event of his<br />

bankruptcy ....... The Act is intended to put all creditors upon an equal<br />

footing. Generally, until a debtor is insolvent or has an act of bankruptcy<br />

in contemplation, he is quite free to deal with his property as he wills and<br />

he may prefer one creditor over another but, upon becoming insolvent, he<br />

can no longer do any act out of the ordinary course of business which has<br />

the effect of preferring a particular creditor over other creditors. If one<br />

creditor receives a preference over other creditors as a result of the debtor<br />

acting intentionally and in fraud of the law, this defeats the equality of the<br />

bankruptcy laws. 8<br />

The following statement from Re Norris, an Alberta Court of Appeal decision,<br />

makes the point even more clearly:<br />

... [the fraud lies in] the accompanying intent of the insolvent debtor who<br />

in the face of imminent bankruptcy is moved to prefer or favor, before<br />

losing control over his assets, a particular creditor over others who will<br />

have to wait for and accept as full payment their rateable share on<br />

distribution by the Trustee in the ensuing bankruptcy. It is called<br />

fraudulent because it prejudices other creditors who will receive<br />

proportionately less, or nothing at all, and upsets the fundamental scheme<br />

of the Act for equal sharing among creditors. 9<br />

Although these explanations are all framed in terms of equal distribution in<br />

bankruptcy, they cannot mean that the objective of preference laws is to ensure<br />

equal distribution per se. The emphasis on the debtor's state of mind and the<br />

reprehensibility of the debtor's conduct is inconsistent with the objective of<br />

preserving equality of distribution per se. All transactions having the effect of<br />

favouring a particular creditor disrupt the equal treatment of creditors in<br />

bankruptcy, regardless of whether the debtor intended that result and regardless of<br />

the moral character of the transaction. Lord Coke's statement discloses the real<br />

6. The Case of Bankrupts (Smith v. Mills) (1584) 76 Eng. Rep. 441, 473 (K.B.). Strictly speaking, this<br />

case concerned the relation back principle (i.e., that the court had the power to avoid transfers after the<br />

debtor had committed an act of bankruptcy), but it provided the general principle from which the law on<br />

fraudulent preferences would develop. Robert Weisberg, Commercial Morality, the Merchant Character<br />

and the History of the Voidable Preference, 39 STAN. L. REV. 3, 40-41 (1986).<br />

7. [1768] 98 Eng. Rep. 165 (K.B.). Lord Coke's statement referred to payments made after the debtor<br />

had become bankrupt, but Lord Mansfield's doctrine extended to transactions on the eve of bankruptcy.<br />

See Harkness v. P'ship Pac. Ltd. [1997] 41 N.S.W. L.R. 204, 237 (Aust.).<br />

8. [1976] 2 S.C.R. 168, para. 21 (Can.). Earlier authorities also emphasized the debtor deterrence<br />

rationale. Can. Credit Men's Trust Ass'n v. Umbel [1931], 13 C.B.R 40, paras. 28, 31 (Can.)<br />

9. [1997] 2 W.W.R. 281, para. 16 (Can.). For more recent statements to the same effect, see<br />

Krawchenko (Trustee of) v. Minister of Nat'l Revenue [2005] 11 C.B.R. (5th) 238, para. 23 (Can.); St.<br />

Anne-Nackawic Pulp Co. (Trustee of) v. Logistec Stevedoring (Atlantic) Inc. [2005] 255 D.L.R. (4th) 137,<br />

para. 11 (Can.).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 663 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:661<br />

concern, namely that it is wrong for the debtor to play favourites among creditors in<br />

defiance of the bankruptcy laws: paying out friends," 0 relatives and business<br />

connections ahead of other creditors is wrong because, given the debtor's impending<br />

bankruptcy, it deprives "other poor men of their true debts." This is where the fraud<br />

lies. Another way of making the same point is to say that the debtor may not "set<br />

himself up as the law-giver in bankruptcy distribution."'" That is how Lord Mansfield<br />

expressed it in Alderson v. Temple." 2<br />

In summary, according to the old cases the rationale for the preference laws is<br />

"debtor deterrence." Under this model, it is the debtor's conduct that is viewed with<br />

suspicion." The debtor deterrence rationale presupposes sanctions against the<br />

preference-giving debtor. The main burden of the preference laws falls on the<br />

creditor rather than the debtor. What penalty does the debtor suffer? In former<br />

times, the giving of a preference was a criminal offence for which the bankrupt<br />

would be pilloried and have an ear cut off. 14 This, along with other barbaric features<br />

of the bankruptcy laws, has long since disappeared, but there are vestiges of a penal<br />

strategy in the modern law. For example, in Canada the giving of a preference is a<br />

ground for denying or suspending the debtor's right of discharge. 5<br />

B. The Creditor Deterrence Rationale<br />

Jackson offers a quite different justification for the preference laws. 6 In his<br />

view, the debtor's insolvency creates a common pool problem. In the absence of<br />

bankruptcy laws, once individual creditors learned about the debtor's insolvency,<br />

each creditor would have an incentive to engage in a race for the debtor's assets both<br />

to make sure of being paid in full and also because, if a creditor does not race and<br />

the other creditors do, it will be left with nothing. This self-interested behaviour is<br />

against the interests of the creditors collectively because it is likely to result in the<br />

piecemeal dismemberment of the debtor's estate, and it is often the case that the<br />

debtor's estate will be worth more if it can be sold intact. Moreover, the prospect of<br />

a race to judgment would require creditors to engage in costly monitoring of not only<br />

the debtor's financial situation but also other creditor's activities to make sure they<br />

did not gain a head start if a race were to eventuate. Bankruptcy law addresses<br />

theses concerns by substituting a mandatory system of collective debt collection for<br />

the individual, winner-take-all collection system that operates outside bankruptcy.<br />

The preference laws are an integral part of the transition from one system to the<br />

other. This is because, in the absence of the preference laws, creditors who find out<br />

about the debtor's impending bankruptcy may take advantage of the information to<br />

have their own claims satisfied, thereby opting out of the collective proceeding<br />

10. "Thus, payment to a creditor who is a family member or friend is more apt than not to qualify as a<br />

fraudulent preference...." St. Anne, supra note 9, para. 11.<br />

11. Weisberg, supra note 6 at 41.<br />

12. Alderson, supra note 7, at 166.<br />

13. See J.J. Morrison, The Impact of Bankruptcy Preference Rules on Commercial Secured Financing<br />

in the United <strong>State</strong>s and Canada, in DEBTOR-CREDITOR LAW: PRACTICE AND DOCTRINE 590 (E. Gertner<br />

& M.A. Springman eds., 1985).<br />

14. 1623, 21 Jac. 1, c. 19, §7 (Eng.), cited in Charles Jordan Tabb, Rethinking Preferences, 43 S.C. L.<br />

REv. 981,996 (1992).<br />

15. Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act, R.S.C., ch. B-3, §173(1)(h) (1985).<br />

16. Thomas H. Jackson, THE LOGIC AND LIMITS OF BANKRUPTCY LAW, 122-50 (1986).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 664 2006-2007


2007<br />

CANADIAN PREFERENCE LAW REFORM<br />

altogether. "By the time the bankruptcy petition is actually filed, those creditors<br />

that remain would have to share in the 'tag ends and remnants' of the [debtor's]<br />

assets."' 7 In short, preference law is "part of the attempt to ameliorate the effects of<br />

a common pool problem that justifies a collective proceeding in the first place."' 8<br />

Lord Coke's justification for the preference laws looks to the debtor's conduct<br />

in giving the preference. By contrast, Jackson's justification looks to the creditor's<br />

conduct in receiving it. While Lord Coke's approach provides a debtor deterrence<br />

rationale for the preference laws, Jackson's approach provides a creditor deterrence<br />

rationale. 9 Under the creditor deterrence model it is the creditor's conduct that is<br />

viewed with suspicion. 0 In the United <strong>State</strong>s over the years, "the focus of the<br />

preference laws has shifted from the culpability of the debtor, to the culpability of<br />

creditors, to the present day standard of strict liability."'" These changes all reflect<br />

different ways of thinking about the preference laws: debtor culpability is consistent<br />

with the debtor deterrence rationale; creditor culpability is consistent with the<br />

creditor deterrence rationale; strict liability is consistent with the idea that the<br />

purpose of the preference laws is to promote equality of distribution per se.<br />

C. The Equal Sharing Rationale<br />

In 1978, the United <strong>State</strong>s moved away from a creditor culpability model.<br />

Congress eliminated the requirement that the creditor recipient have reasonable<br />

cause to believe that the debtor was insolvent and, in its place, introduced a strict<br />

liability regime. The move was justified in the following terms:<br />

Whether or not a creditor knows or believes that his debtor is sliding into<br />

bankruptcy is important if the only purpose of the preference section is to<br />

deter the race. However, a creditor's state of mind has nothing<br />

whatsoever to do with the policy of equality of distribution, and whether<br />

or not he knows of the debtor's insolvency does little to comfort other<br />

creditors similarly situated who will receive that much less from the<br />

debtor's estate as a result of the prebankruptcy transfer to the preferred<br />

creditor. To argue that the creditor's state of mind is an important<br />

element of a preference and that creditors should not be required to<br />

disgorge what they took in supposed innocence is to ignore the strong<br />

bankruptcy policy of equality among creditors. 22<br />

17. Id. at 125, quoting Collier's on Bankruptcy, 744 §60.01 (14th ed., 1977).<br />

18. Id. See also Richard H. McLaren, Voidable Transactions in Bankruptcy: The Canadian<br />

Perspective, in CURRENT DEVELOPMENTS IN INTERNATIONAL AND COMPARATIVE CORPORATE<br />

INSOLVENCY LAW 372 (J. Ziegel ed., 1994).<br />

19. In Hudson v. Benallack [1976] 2 S.C.R. 168 (Can.), the Supreme Court of Canada emphasized the<br />

requirement in the BIA preference provisions for proof of the debtor's intention, while at the same time<br />

denying any requirement for proof of the creditor's concurrent intention. Both aspects of the decision are<br />

consistent with the debtor deterrence rationale for the preference laws.<br />

20. See Morrison, supra note 13, at 590.<br />

21. Scott Blakeley, A History of Bankruptcy Preferences 1 (American Bankruptcy Reform Study<br />

Project, 1995).<br />

22. H.R. Rep. No. 595 at 178 (1977). The United <strong>State</strong>s had earlier (in the 19th century) abandoned<br />

debtor deterrence in favour of a creditor culpability model. See Weisberg, supra note 6, at 85; Tabb, supra<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 665 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:661<br />

In other words, strict liability supports a policy of equal sharing. The reference<br />

to equality cannot be taken literally because the principle of equality, as embodied in<br />

the pari passu rule, is largely a myth in modern bankruptcy law. The exceptions<br />

(insolvency set-off, preferential claims, deferred claims and so on, in conjunction<br />

with the prevalence of secured credit) are so extensive that they all but swallow the<br />

rule. The only claimants subject to the pari passu rule are the general unsecured<br />

creditors, but in the overwhelming majority of bankruptcy cases there is nothing left<br />

to distribute among the general unsecured creditors once secured and preferred<br />

creditors have been paid out. Bearing these considerations in mind, the equal<br />

sharing rationale presumably means that creditors should share in accordance with<br />

the overall scheme of distribution provided for in bankruptcy laws. 3<br />

In any event, contrary to the impression the quoted passage creates, the current<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s preference provisions do not unequivocally embrace the equal sharing<br />

rationale (whatever equal sharing might mean). The Bankruptcy Code, § 547(c)(2)<br />

creates an exception to preference liability for transfers in the ordinary course of<br />

business. The purpose of the ordinary course exception has been explained in the<br />

following terms:<br />

The purpose of this exception is to leave undisturbed normal financial<br />

relations, because it does not detract from the general policy of the<br />

preference section to discourage unusual action by either the debtor or his<br />

creditors during the debtor's slide into bankruptcy. 24<br />

In other words, "only extraordinary behavior by creditors who are seeking to<br />

'opt out' of the bankruptcy scheme should be condemned by preference law." 25 So,<br />

it seems that the aim of the preference laws is not to promote equal distribution<br />

between creditors. Creditor deterrence is still the objective. It is true that the 1978<br />

law eliminated the "reasonable cause to believe" test on the express ground that the<br />

creditor's intentions are irrelevant to the goal of equal distribution. However, "by<br />

creating the ordinary course exception in the 1978 law, Congress indirectly<br />

resurrected the same core principle of culpability. 2 6<br />

There is similar ambivalence in other common law countries about the goals of<br />

the preference laws. For example, according to the Australian <strong>Law</strong> Reform<br />

Commission, the preference laws reflect "two fundamental principles of insolvency<br />

law - that of equal sharing between creditors and that of promoting an orderly<br />

process both during and immediately preceding the formal insolvency<br />

administration." 27 However, the Australian preference provisions focus on creditor<br />

note 14 at 982 n.1.<br />

23. Rizwaan Jameel Mokal, CORPORATE INSOLVENCY LAW: THEORY AND APPLICATION 96-100,<br />

326-28 (2005); Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook, The Control of Wealth in Bankruptcy, 82 TEX. L. REV. 795, 822-24<br />

(2004); see also Roy Goode, PRINCIPLES OF CORPORATE INSOLVENCY LAW 411 (3d ed., 2005).<br />

24. H.R. Rep. No. 595, supra note 22, at 373.<br />

25. Charles Jordan Tabb, THE LAW OF BANKRUPTCY 383 (1977).<br />

26. Id. Elsewhere Tabb goes so far as to say that the ordinary course of business exception does<br />

"extreme violence to the "equality" goal of the preference law. Charles Jordan Tabb, The Brave New<br />

World of Bankruptcy Preferences, 13 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 425, 440 (Winter 2005); see also New<br />

Zealand Ministry of Economic Development, Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> Review: Tier One Discussion Documents at<br />

68 (2001) (defences inherently undermine pari passu goal of a strict liability regime).<br />

27. Australian <strong>Law</strong> Reform Commission, General Insolvency Inquiry Report No. 45, at 267 (1988).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 666 2006-2007


2007<br />

CANADIAN PREFERENCE LAW REFORM<br />

culpability and this is inconsistent with the equal sharing rationale."' The ALRC<br />

went on to say that abandoning the preference laws "would deliberately favour and<br />

encourage creditors who quite legally extracted payments from the debtor - even at<br />

the eleventh hour." 29 This last statement implies that creditor deterrence is the real<br />

objective and that current legislation is consistent with the creditor deterrence<br />

rationale. By contrast, the English preference provisions focus on debtor<br />

culpability, 3 ' reflecting a commitment to the debtor deterrence rationale." However,<br />

the English provisions have been criticized for being out of step with modern<br />

bankruptcy policy. 32<br />

D. Finality of Transactions<br />

There is tension between the goals of preference laws and the need for finality<br />

of transactions. "From a commercial perspective, it is appropriate to encourage<br />

debtors to pay creditors. It is also important that a creditor be able to rely on the<br />

validity of a payment. Commercial transactions should not be lightly interfered<br />

with." 33 Another possible explanation for the ordinary course exception in United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s preference laws is that it represents a trade-off between the goals of equal<br />

sharing and finality of transactions?' A strict liability preference law threatens the<br />

finality of transactions because it means that creditors can never be sure that their<br />

payments will be immune from attack. This uncertainty adds to creditors' costs and<br />

it is likely to be reflected in the cost and availability of credit. The ordinary course<br />

exception addresses this problem in part by limiting liability to cases where the<br />

creditor knows about the debtor's insolvency.<br />

It has been suggested that a better response to the finality of transactions<br />

concern might be to shorten the review period." However, while a shorter review<br />

period may limit creditors' exposure, it does not assist them in managing the risk.<br />

This is because creditors may have no way of knowing at the time of receiving the<br />

payment whether it falls within the review period.<br />

E. Facilitating the Provision of Credit to Financially Distressed Debtors<br />

The finality of transactions concern is a function of the strict liability preference<br />

law model. It does not arise if the law requires proof of either debtor or creditor<br />

culpability because in both these regimes creditors have the means of knowing in<br />

28. Bankruptcy Act no. 33 1966 § 122(1)(a), Commonwealth Consolidated Acts (Austl.);<br />

Corporations Act 2001, § 588FG(2).<br />

29. Australian <strong>Law</strong> Reform Commission, supra note 27, at 267.<br />

30. Insolvency Act, supra note 15 (1986) § 239.<br />

31. Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> Review Committee, Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> and Practice, June 1982, at 285, paras. 1254 et<br />

seq.<br />

32. Goode, supra note 23, at 456-57.<br />

33. <strong>Law</strong> Reform Commission of British Columbia, Report on Fraudulent Conveyances and<br />

Preferences (LRC No. 94, 1988), 120.<br />

34. Tabb, THE LAW OF BANKRUPTCY, supra note 25, at 385; but see the difficulties New Zealand<br />

encountered with the ordinary course of business exception, discussed infra notes 114 and ll5and<br />

accompanying text.<br />

35. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 667 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:661<br />

advance whether a payment may be subject to attack. A possible conclusion is that<br />

an ordinary course exception is unnecessary unless strict liability is the rule.<br />

However, this presupposes that the purpose of the ordinary course exception is<br />

to facilitate the provision of credit outside the review period. There is an alternative<br />

construction, namely that the purpose is to facilitate the provision of credit inside the<br />

review period. "Allowing creditors to obtain ordinary course payments actually<br />

encourages them to do business on a credit basis with a financially distressed debtor.<br />

As a result, the debtor may be able to stay afloat and avoid bankruptcy entirely, or<br />

at least hold a stronger financial condition when it does go into bankruptcy. 3 6 In<br />

other words, the function of the ordinary course exception is to maximize the value<br />

of the debtor's estate for the benefit of all the creditors and current United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

bankruptcy law trades off this objective against the equal sharing goal.<br />

On this analysis, the ordinary course exception is not simply a function of the<br />

strict liability rule and may have a role to play in other regimes as well. For example,<br />

lawmakers who opt for a debtor culpability regime may want to incorporate an<br />

ordinary course exception in order to strike a trade-off between debtor deterrence<br />

on the one hand, and facilitating the provision of credit to financially distressed<br />

debtors on the other. Likewise, the incorporation of an ordinary course exception in<br />

a creditor culpability regime may signal a willingness to sacrifice some creditor<br />

deterrence in exchange for the stimulus to lending the exception provides.<br />

Still, it is not certain that such trade-offs yield net benefits. Some<br />

commentators argue that the ordinary course exception may have perverse incentive<br />

effects and that, far from encouraging creditors to deal with financially distressed<br />

debtors, it may actually discourage them. The argument is that a creditor who gets<br />

paid in the ordinary course need not co-operate further with the debtor because if<br />

the debtor goes into bankruptcy, the creditor can simply keep the payment and not<br />

extend more credit. 7 A related argument is that the ordinary course exception may<br />

have a chilling effect on the provision of credit to financially stable debtors, and this<br />

more than offsets the benefits of more freely available credit to debtors who are<br />

financially distressed. 3 "<br />

F. The Trade-Offs<br />

There are different schools of thought in the United <strong>State</strong>s on the trade-offs the<br />

ordinary course exception involves. Some favour the present law, with or without<br />

relatively minor modifications? 9 Others argue that the exception should be repealed<br />

36. Id. at 384.<br />

37. Id.<br />

38. Id. at 384-85.<br />

39. This school of thought represents the prevailing wisdom. The Bankruptcy Abuse and Consumer<br />

Protection Act of 2005, Pub. L No.109-8, Stat.23 (2005) [hereinafter BAPCPA] extensively amended the<br />

Bankruptcy Code, but made only relatively minor changes to the preference provision. In particular, the<br />

ordinary course exception was retained subject only to removal of the requirement for the creditor to show<br />

that the transaction was made both "in the ordinary course of business or financial affairs of the debtor and<br />

the creditor" and "made according to ordinary business terms." Id. Under the new provision a creditor<br />

will only have to show that the transaction was made "in the ordinary course of business or financial affairs<br />

of the debtor and the transferee" or that it was made "made according to ordinary business terms." In the<br />

past, courts have interpreted the first part of the test as referring to ordinariness in a subjective sense and<br />

the second part of the test as incorporating an objective standard in relation to industry at large. Tabb,<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 668 2006-2007


2007<br />

CANADIAN PREFERENCE LAW REFORM<br />

to recognize the goal of equal sharing among creditors is paramount." At the<br />

opposite end of the spectrum, some argue for a repeal of preference laws on the<br />

ground that they are not cost-effective.<br />

For example, McCoid contends that the objective of preference laws is creditor<br />

deterrence, but the laws fail to deter because the sanction is inadequate. If the<br />

trustee brings a successful preference action, the only consequence is that the<br />

creditor must return the payment. Except to the extent that the creditor has<br />

expended resources either obtaining the preference in the first place or defending<br />

the action, it is no worse off after returning the preference than it would have been<br />

had it never received the preference in the first place.' A possible rejoinder is that<br />

the argument over-states the case for abolition. Creditors' expenditure on obtaining<br />

the preference in the first place and subsequently fighting to keep it are dead-weight<br />

costs. The prospect of incurring these costs has some deterrent effect, and so the<br />

problem is one of under-deterrence rather than no deterrence at all. Underdeterrence<br />

is better than no deterrence at all, which would certainly be the result if<br />

the preference laws were repealed.<br />

In the course of its General Insolvency Inquiry, the Australian <strong>Law</strong> Reform<br />

Commission received a submission from Justice Pincus, a judge of the Federal Court<br />

of Australia, recommending repeal of preference provisions on the ground that the<br />

costs of litigating preference claims defeat the underlying policy objectives. 3 Alan<br />

Schwartz offers a more sophisticated version of the same argument:"'<br />

(1) The creditor deterrence rationale for preference laws is misguided because<br />

creditors cannot force a financially distressed firm to pay preferences. Creditors can<br />

threaten attachment to try and force the debtor to pay, but the debtor can credibly<br />

respond by threatening to file for bankruptcy and thus stay all attachments.<br />

Therefore, if preference laws were repealed, distressed debtors would pay<br />

preferences because they wanted to, not because they had to;<br />

(2) The debtor deterrence rationale has no purchase unless the debtor expects<br />

to be liquidated. Otherwise, the debtor will want to settle with its creditors, and<br />

non-preferred creditors will not accept in settlement an amount less than their pro<br />

rata bankruptcy payoffs. "In other words, "the pro rata rule precludes a firm<br />

interested in survival from paying today what are defined as preferences.<br />

Consequently, a separate prohibition against preferences does not materially<br />

increase a financially distressed firm's commitment to the pro rata rule"; 5<br />

(3) If a debtor firm expects to be liquidated, it will be indifferent as to how its<br />

assets are distributed among creditors because the firm will disappear with certainty.<br />

However, the firm's principals may not be indifferent. They may cause the firm to<br />

pay particular creditors to ensure goodwill for themselves, in consequence of a<br />

Brave New World, supra note 26, at 440-42.<br />

40. See, e.g., Tabb, Rethinking Preferences, supra note 14, at 987.<br />

41. John C. McCoid, II, Bankruptcy, Preferences and Efficiency: An Expression of Doubt, 67 VA. L.<br />

REV. 249 (1981).<br />

42. Jackson, supra note 16, at 137-38.<br />

43. Australian <strong>Law</strong> Reform Commission, supra note 27, at 267.<br />

44. Alan Schwartz, A Normative Theory of Business Bankruptcy, 91 VA. L. REV. 1199, 1224-31<br />

45. Id. at 1226.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 669 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:661<br />

personal relationship or to avoid liability exposure if a principal has guaranteed the<br />

firm's debt;<br />

(4) Actions to recover preferences paid in these circumstances are inefficient<br />

both ex post and ex ante. They are ex post inefficient because they cost money,<br />

thereby diminishing the value of the bankruptcy estate: "redistributing the assets of a<br />

failed firm among its general creditors amounts to redecorating the Titanic's salon";1 6<br />

(5) Abolition of the preference laws would save the costs of redistributing the<br />

firm's assets, thereby increasing the collective returns to creditors in future. The<br />

prospect of higher collective returns in bankruptcy should result in lower borrowing<br />

costs. Conversely, preference laws increase borrowing costs and are ex ante<br />

inefficient.<br />

Critics might take issue with step (1) of Schwartz's argument on the ground that<br />

it too readily assumes a debtor's willingness to play the bankruptcy card. Unless the<br />

debtor expects to be liquidated, it will want to maintain good relations with its key<br />

suppliers and creditors. Threatening to file for bankruptcy in response to a creditor's<br />

demand for payment is not conducive to maintaining good relations. Of course, if<br />

the debtor realizes its hopes of staying in business, the preference question will go<br />

away. On the other hand, the debtor's hopes may not be realized. Financially<br />

distressed debtors have a tendency to over-estimate their chances of recovery and<br />

creditors may exploit the debtor's self-deception to extract preferential payments. 47<br />

Step (4) amounts to an implicit rejection of both the debtor deterrence rationale and<br />

the equal sharing rationale for the preference laws; critics might take issue with this<br />

because it summarily discounts non-economic arguments in support of preference<br />

laws. 48 It is worth noting that the Australian <strong>Law</strong> Reform Commission rejected<br />

Justice Pincus's proposal for repeal of preference laws on the ground that it "would<br />

do much to undermine two fundamental principles of insolvency law - that of equal<br />

sharing between creditors and that of promoting an orderly process both during and<br />

immediately preceding the formal insolvency administration." 49<br />

A. Introduction<br />

III. CURRENT CANADIAN LAW<br />

The Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act, § 95 provides in part as follows:<br />

1) Every transfer of property, every charge made on property, every<br />

payment made, every obligation incurred and every judicial proceeding<br />

taken or suffered by any insolvent person in favour of any creditor or of<br />

any person in trust for any creditor with a view to giving that creditor a<br />

preference over the other creditors is, when it is made, given, incurred,<br />

46. Id.<br />

47. See Canadawide Fruit Wholesalers Inc.(Trustee of) v. Hapco Farms Inc. [1998] A.C.W.S.J. 522010<br />

(Que. CA).<br />

48. See, e.g., Tabb, Rethinking Preferences, supra note 14 (arguing for preference laws on distributive<br />

grounds).<br />

49. Australian <strong>Law</strong> Reform Commission, supra note 27, at 267. For a similar response in the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s, see Charles Jordan Tabb, Panglossian Preference Paradigm? 5 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 407, 420<br />

(1997).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 670 2006-2007


2007<br />

CANADIAN PREFERENCE LAW REFORM<br />

taken or suffered within the period beginning on the day that is three<br />

months before the date of the initial bankruptcy event and ending on the<br />

date the insolvent person became bankrupt, both dates included, deemed<br />

fraudulent and void as against, or in the Province of Quebec, may not be<br />

set up against, the trustee in the bankruptcy.<br />

(2) If any transfer, charge, payment, obligation or judicial proceeding<br />

mentioned in subsection (1) has the effect of giving any creditor a<br />

preference over other creditors, or over any one or more of them, it shall<br />

be presumed, in the absence of evidence to the contrary, to have been<br />

made, incurred, taken, paid or suffered with a view to giving the creditor a<br />

preference over other creditors, whether or not it was made voluntarily or<br />

under pressure and evidence of pressure shall not be admissible to support<br />

the transaction.<br />

Section 96 provides:<br />

If the transfer, charge, payment, obligation or judicial proceeding<br />

mentioned in section 95 is in favour of a person related to the insolvent<br />

person, the period referred to in subsection 95(1) shall be one year instead<br />

of three months. °<br />

50. Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act, R.S.C. c. 27 (1992) G39, § 4(2) provides in part as follows:<br />

(2) For the purposes of this Act, persons are related to each other and are "related persons" if<br />

they are<br />

(a) individuals connected by blood relationship, marriage, common-law partnership or<br />

adoption;<br />

(b) a corporation and<br />

(i) a person who controls the corporation, if it is controlled by one person,<br />

(ii) a person who is a member of a related group that controls the corporation, or<br />

(c) two corporations<br />

(iii) any person connected in the manner set out in paragraph (a) to a person<br />

described in subparagraph (i) or (ii); or<br />

(i) controlled by the same person or group of persons,<br />

(ii) each of which is controlled by one person and the person who controls one of<br />

the corporations is related to the person who controls the other corporation,<br />

(iii) one of which is controlled by one person and that person is related to any<br />

member of a related group that controls the other corporation,<br />

(iv) one of which is controlled by one person and that person is related to each<br />

member of an unrelated group that controls the other corporation,<br />

(v) one of which is controlled by a related group a member of which is related to<br />

each member of an unrelated group that controls the other corporation, or<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 671 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:661<br />

These provisions have survived virtually unchanged for nearly a century, and<br />

they have generated a substantial amount of litigation."<br />

The main features of the provisions, as amplified by the case law, are as<br />

follows: 5 2<br />

(1) For the sections to apply, there must be both a preference in fact and an<br />

intention on the debtor's part to prefer the creditor;<br />

(2) The test for determining the debtor's intention is an objective one, in other<br />

words, the courts infer the debtor's intention from its conduct and the surrounding<br />

circumstances; 53<br />

(3) It follows that "fraudulent" does not mean actual fraud, but constructive or<br />

legal fraud. Constructive fraud is conduct the law characterizes as fraudulent, not<br />

because it is actually dishonest, but because it is against the public interest; 4<br />

(4) The evidentiary burden is on the trustee to prove a preference in fact, but it<br />

is on the creditor to prove that the debtor did not have the necessary intention;" 5<br />

(5) A creditor cannot rebut the presumption of intention by leading evidence<br />

that the creditor pressured the debtor into making the transfer; 5 6<br />

(6) On the other hand, the law does not penalize a diligent creditor and<br />

evidence showing that the debtor made the payment to stay an aggressive creditor<br />

may be enough to rebut the presumption.; 5 1<br />

(vi) one of which is controlled by an unrelated group each member of which is<br />

related to at least one member of an unrelated group that controls the other<br />

corporation.<br />

51. Houlden and Morawetz speculate that "[tihere have probably been more reported cases on § 95<br />

than on any other section of the Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act." Lloyd W. Houlden and Geoffrey B.<br />

Morawetz, THE 2006 ANNOTATED BANKRUPTCY AND INSOLVENCY ACT (2006), para. F § 89. There are<br />

numerous cases from England and cases decided under the provincial preference provisions as well: see<br />

M.A. Springman, Fraudulent Conveyances, Fraudulent Preferences, and Other Voidable Transactions,<br />

<strong>Law</strong> Society of Upper Canada, Special Lectures, 59, 61 (1988).<br />

52. See Houlden and Morawetz, supra note 51, at para. F §§ 89,106.4; Melvin A. Springman et al.,<br />

FRAUDULENT CONVEYANCES AND PREFERENCES (1994), ch. 20.<br />

53. See, e.g., St Anne, supra note 9, at 142. Not all cases have adopted an objective test. See<br />

Springman et al., supra note 52, at 20-31 to 20-36 (noting four different views of the nature of intent to<br />

prefer but arguing that, on balance, the authorities support an objective test).<br />

54. See generally Lloyd W. Houlden, O.C., Fraudulent Bankrupts and Bankruptcies, 5 Can. Bankr.<br />

Rep. 207 (1963) (on the different types of fraud in bankruptcy).<br />

55. In order to raise the presumption that there has been a fraudulent preference the trustee must<br />

prove three things: (a) payment must have been made within three months of bankruptcy; (b) the debtor<br />

was insolvent at the time of payment; and (c) as a result of the payment the creditor must have in fact<br />

received a preference over the other creditors. Re Van der Like, [1970] 14 C.B.R. (N.S.) 229, 299 (Can.).<br />

When the trustee has proven these three elements, "he need proceed no further and the onus is then on the<br />

creditor to satisfy the court, if he can, that there was no intent on the part of the debtor to give a<br />

preference." Id. at 230.<br />

56. Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act, supra note 50, at § 92(5). For applications, see St. Anne, supra<br />

note 9, at 142; Re Bridal Boutique Ltd., [1980], 36 C.B.R. (N.S.) 134, 135 (Can.); Medler-McKay Holdings<br />

Ltd. (Trustee of) v. Teac Canada Ltd., [1994] 26 C.B.R. (3d) 147, para. 3 (Can.); see also N. German,<br />

Bankruptcy-Pressure as a Defence-Fraudulent Preferences, 8 ALTA. L. REV. 154 (1970).<br />

57. See, e.g., Re Norris [1994] 28 C.B.R. (3d) 167, para. 9-10 (Can.), rev'd on other grounds [1996] 2.<br />

W.W.R. 281,287 (Can.); see also Re Houston and Thornton [1973], 18 C.B.R. (NS) 102, 104 (Can.); Re Les<br />

Bois de la Malbaie Lt6e [1980] 36 C.B.R. (N.S.) 85, 86 (Can.); cf Krawchenko, supra note 9, para. 22-23.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 672 2006-2007


2007<br />

CANADIAN PREFERENCE LAW REFORM<br />

(7) Alternatively, the creditor may rebut the presumption of intention with<br />

leading evidence to show that the transaction was in the ordinary course of the<br />

debtor's business." There is an element of tautology here because the absence of an<br />

intention to prefer is a sine qua non of the conclusion that the transaction was in the<br />

ordinary course of business. Typically, payments in the ordinary course of business<br />

are made for one of two reasons: (1) so that the debtor can take advantage of<br />

favourable payment terms; or (2) to ensure that the creditor continues to supply the<br />

debtor with goods or services so the debtor can continue in business; 9<br />

(8) The debtor's belief that the payment will allow it to continue in business<br />

must be a reasonable one. The reasonableness of the debtor's belief is a matter for<br />

the court, having regard for the evidence.;'<br />

(9) Proof that the debtor did not know it was insolvent at the time of the<br />

transaction is admissible to rebut the presumption of intention, but it is not<br />

conclusive given that' the courts apply an objective test in determining the debtor's<br />

intention; 6<br />

(10) Proof that the creditor intended to receive a preference is neither a<br />

necessary nor a sufficient requirement for avoidance of the transaction; 6 1<br />

(11) On the other hand, evidence that the creditor knew of the debtor's<br />

insolvency is admissible as tending to show that the transaction was not in the<br />

ordinary course of business and that the debtor's intention was to prefer the<br />

creditor; 63 and<br />

(12) If the creditor is related to the debtor, the review period is one year instead<br />

of 3 months and, in addition, the courts will require stronger evidence to support the<br />

bona fides of the transaction.' 4<br />

58. See, e.g., Re Pac. Mobile Corp. [1985] 1 S.C.R. 290 (S.C.C.); see also St. Anne, supra note 9, at 146;<br />

Re Claude Cayouette Inc. [1983] 48 C.B.R. (N.S.) 89, 96 (Can.). The ordinary course of business is an<br />

"abstract" standard that requires the court "to evaluate the particular circumstances of each case in order<br />

to determine the quality of a given transaction." Re Pacific Mobile [1985] 1 S.C.R. 290, 291 (Can.) (trans.<br />

from French). In Re Pacific Mobile the Supreme Court of Canada refrained from giving a "comprehensive<br />

definition of the term 'ordinary course of business' for all transactions." Id. The court preferred to<br />

"consider the circumstances of each case and to take into account the type of business carried on between<br />

the debtor and creditor." Id.; see also Cargill v. Compton Agro Inc. [1998] 7 C.B.R. (4th) 132 (Can.), rev'd<br />

on other grounds [2000] 16 C.B.R. (4th) 35 (Can.); Deloitte Touche Inc. v. White Veal Meat Packers Ltd.<br />

[2000] 16 C.B.R. (4th) 74, para. 12 (Can.), affd 21 C.B.R. (4th) 234 (Can.).<br />

59. Re Norris, supra note 57, para. 7.<br />

60. Re Yorkville Homes Ltd. [1986], 62 C.B.R. (N.S.) 70, 73 (Can.); Re Spectrum Interiors (Guelph)<br />

Ltd. [1979] 29 C.B.R. (N.S.) 218 (Can.); Principal Group Ltd. (Trustee of) v. Anderson [1994] 29 C.B.R.<br />

(3d) 216, paras 52-58 (Can.), affd on other grounds [1997] 46 C.B.R. (3d) 101 (Can.); Canadawide Fruit,<br />

supra note 47. However, there is a line of cases that adopt a more subjective approach. See infra note 84.<br />

61. See, e.g., Cargill Ltd., supra note 58; see also Re Moureaux, Hauspy, Forrest Design Inc. [1995], 33<br />

C.B.R. (3d) 42, para. 15 (Can.).<br />

62. See, e.g., Benallack, supra note 19 (discussing that concurrent intent on the part of the debtor and<br />

creditor is not required).<br />

63. See, e.g., Re Royal City Chrysler Plymouth Ltd. [1995], 30 C.B.R. 3d 178, paras. 66-69 (Can.);<br />

Kisluk v. B.L. Armstrong Co. [1982], 44 C.B.R. (N.S.) 251, para 57 (Can.).<br />

64. See §§ 96, 4(2) (definition of related person). See, e.g., Re Garrett [1979], 30 C.B.R. (N.S.) 150,<br />

paras. 18-19 (Can.); see also Re Litvack [1962], 3 C.B.R. (N.S.) 272 (Can.); and Re Norris, supra note 57,<br />

paras. 20-21.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 673 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:661<br />

B. Pressure and diligence<br />

As indicated above, a creditor cannot rebut the presumption of intention by<br />

demonstrating that the creditor pressured the debtor into making the payment. This<br />

is a statutory rule, and its legislative history is instructive.<br />

Parliament eliminated the doctrine of pressure in 1920.65 The doctrine enabled<br />

a more aggressive, active or insensitive creditor to "reap the benefits of his<br />

harassment of the debtor" at the expense of more patient or hesitant creditors. 66<br />

Fraudulent preference law, as developed by Lord Mansfield, required the debtor's<br />

transfer or payment to be a voluntary one. According to Lord Mansfield, if a<br />

creditor demands payment, "or sues [the debtor], or threatens [the debtor], without<br />

fraud, the preference is good., 67<br />

Prior to 1920 Canadian courts followed the English doctrine of pressure holding<br />

that there was no voluntary act on the part of the debtor where payment is "brought<br />

about by the active influence of the creditor., 68 However, what amounted to<br />

pressure in any particular case was "always a question of fact and one difficult to<br />

make out. ' 69 A mere request by a creditor, which induces action on the part of the<br />

debtor, might amount to pressure in the eyes of the court." Where the debtor and<br />

creditor knew each other and were familiar with the law collusion remained a real<br />

possibility. 7 ' Courts accepted that the doctrine of pressure validated the transaction<br />

even if this had the effect of giving one creditor a preference over another. 72<br />

In 1919, Parliament debated a comprehensive bill to restore a national<br />

bankruptcy regime. 73 Bill 18 proposed to "eliminate entirely the doctrine of pressure<br />

as a defence to a preferential transaction." 74 However, abolition of the doctrine did<br />

not prove easy and legislative history of the 'no pressure' clause provision illustrates<br />

the extent to which the doctrine of pressure had benefited creditors. In the course of<br />

65. An Act to Amend, supra note 2, at 123.<br />

66. See Springman, Fraudulent Conveyances, supra note 51, at 141.<br />

67. Alderson, supra note 7, at 166.<br />

68. Stephens v. McArthur [1891] 19 S.C.R. 446, para. 12 (Can.). After Parliament repealed the<br />

national Insolvent Act of 1875, many provinces enacted Assignments and Preference legislation. Pressure<br />

remained relevant under the provincial case law. Id.<br />

69. Brayley v. Ellis [1884], 9 O.A.R. 565,573 (Can.); Ivey & Co. v. Knox, Morgan & Co. [1885], 8 OR.<br />

635, 646 (Can.) ("The earlier cases no doubt are rather lax with respect to what will constitute pressure..<br />

."); Re Hurst [1876] O.J. No. 441 at para. 47 (Ont. P.C.); see also C.B. Labatt, "The Doctrine of Pressure"<br />

[1899] 35 C.L.J. 322; R.S. Cassels, "Mercantile Preferences" [1891] 11 C.L.T. 61.<br />

70. Molson Bank v. Halter [1890] 18 S.C.R. 88, para. 6 (Can.); Stephens, supra note 68, para. 13; see<br />

also Springman et. al., supra note 52, at 18-22. For the Chief Justice of the Ontario Court of Appeal,<br />

extending the doctrine of pressure to a mere demand "amounted in some cases to a scandal." Webster v.<br />

Crickmore [1898], 25 O.A.R. 97, 105 (Can.).<br />

71. Meriden Silver Co. v. Lee & Chillas [1882], 2 OR. 451 (Can.) (where the court discovered actual<br />

collusion). See also Re Carson [1924], 4 D.L.R. 492, para. 17 (Can.).<br />

72. See Gordon v. Young [1866], 12 Gr. 318, para. 5 (Can.). See also Davidson v. Ross [1876], 24 Gr.<br />

22, para 144 (Can.) (The Court of Chancery of Ontario rejected the doctrine of pressure on the basis that it<br />

was opposed to the principle of equal treatment of creditors). But see McCrae v. White [1883] 9 S.C.R. 22,<br />

para. 10 (in which the Supreme Court of Canada disapproved the decision in Davidson v. Ross).<br />

73. Bill 18, An Act Respecting Bankruptcy, Second Session, <strong>13th</strong> Parliament, 9-10 George V, 1919<br />

(First Reading March 6, 1919). In 1888, Parliament had repealed the Insolvent Act of 1875 (repealed S.C.<br />

1880, c.1), leaving Canada without a national bankruptcy regime for nearly forty years.<br />

74. H.P. Grundy, "Synopsis of the Canadian Bankruptcy Act" (1920-21), 1 C.B.R. 325, 338. H.P.<br />

Grundy was the original drafter of the Bill. See Bill 18, cl.31(3).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 674 2006-2007


2007<br />

CANADIAN PREFERENCE LAW REFORM<br />

parliamentary hearings, the "'no pressure"' clause was struck out leaving the<br />

doctrine of pressure as the status quo. 75 During the hearings, commercial groups and<br />

the banking industry objected to the abolition of the doctrine. They advocated the<br />

retention of the English model which would enable creditors to invoke the doctrine<br />

to validate transactions." In 1920 Parliament restored the "no pressure" clause, and<br />

since then the statutory preference provision has largely remained the same. 7 1<br />

Although Parliament intended to eradicate the doctrine of pressure by<br />

specifically legislating that evidence of pressure is not admissible to support the<br />

transaction, the courts have since allowed indirect evidence of what might otherwise<br />

be considered pressure. For example, the courts have read a creditor diligence<br />

defence into the statute: a creditor may lead evidence of its own diligence to rebut<br />

the presumption of the debtor's intention to prefer. In Re Totem Painting Company<br />

Limited," 8 the court attempted to distinguish between diligence and pressure. A<br />

creditor had accepted an overdue payment on account with knowledge of the<br />

debtor's financial position. The court concluded that the creditor:<br />

"... may have applied some pressure but, while pressure is no longer a<br />

defence to a charge of fraudulent preference, it has not yet been shifted to<br />

the opposite pole of being considered proof of fraud. Creditors may be<br />

penalized for dishonesty, but surely not for diligence." 9<br />

On the other hand, contrary to what this statement implies, there is no sharp<br />

dividing line between pressure and diligence and so the creditor diligence defence<br />

may be a means of reintroducing the doctrine of pressure by the back door."<br />

However, the scope of the defence is unsettled. In Re Hewston & Thornton, 81 the<br />

court concluded that<br />

there was no intention on the part of the debtors to prefer the two respondents.<br />

I find that the debtors were hopeful ... that they would be able to keep their<br />

business in operation. The only reason for making the payment to the<br />

75. Debates of the Senate (June 5, 1919), at 650; House of Commons Debates (May 15, 1919), at 2470-<br />

71.<br />

76. House of Commons Debates (15 May 1919), at 2470-71(referring to a number of protests including<br />

submissions from commercial bodies). H.P. Grundy, "Synopsis of the Canadian Bankruptcy Act" (1920-<br />

21), 1 C.B.R. 325, 337 (referring to opposition of banking interests).<br />

77. See An Act to Amend, supra note 2, at 123. Pressure continues to remain relevant under some<br />

provincial Assignment and Preferences legislation. See, e.g., Bank of Montreal v. Ngo [1985], 56 C.B.R.<br />

(N.S.) 66 (Can.).<br />

78. [1960] 32 W.W.R. 143 (Can.).<br />

79. Id. at 144.<br />

80. Cf. Labatt, supra note 69, at 356 ("the theory upon which the law recognizes [pressure] viz., that<br />

the active, diligent creditor who is prompt to secure himself the moment his debtor falls into difficulties is a<br />

highly meritorious personage, is certainly not beyond dispute" (emphasis added)). In Alderson, supra note<br />

7, at 168, Lord Mansfield asked of whether in any particular case a debtor prefers a creditor: "[b]ut that<br />

will depend upon the act. As, if a bankrupt, in course of payment pays a creditor; this is a fair advantage, in<br />

the course of trade: or, if a creditor threatens legal diligence, and there is no collusion; or begins to sue a<br />

debtor: and he makes an assignment of part of his goods; it is a fair transaction..." (emphasis added). See<br />

also Harman v. Fishar [1774] 98 Eng. Rep. 998, 1001 ([o]r suppose legal diligence used by a creditor, and an<br />

execution ... and under terror of that he makes an assignment and delivery of his effects, it would be valid;<br />

the object not being to give a preference, but to deliver himself" (emphasis added)).<br />

81. [1973] 18 C.B.R. (N.S.) 102 (Can).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 675 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:661<br />

respondents was because the respondents were pressing more vigorously than<br />

other creditors for payment of their accounts.2<br />

So stated, the diligent creditor defence is inconsistent with the express statutory<br />

provision excluding evidence of pressure. On the other hand, in Re Norris," the<br />

court held that for the diligent creditor defence to apply, there must be an imminent<br />

threat of crisis unless the debtor responds to the creditor's demand. In Re Norris<br />

itself, the defence failed because the court found that the creditor had not acted<br />

aggressively enough." In other words, evidence of pressure may or may not be<br />

admissible to support the transaction depending on the amount of pressure the<br />

creditor has applied.<br />

The courts have also been prepared to excuse transactions in the ordinary<br />

course of business and this trend, too, compromises the rule that evidence of<br />

pressure is not admissible to support the transaction. For example, a creditor may<br />

refuse to ship goods until the debtor pays for earlier deliveries. This is clearly a form<br />

of pressure, but the court may uphold the transaction on the ground that the<br />

payment was not to prefer the creditor but, rather, to obtain the supply of goods or<br />

services."<br />

C. Assessment<br />

According to Dickson J. in the Benallack case, the policy underlying the<br />

Canadian preference provisions is debtor deterrence.8 6 However, while it is true that<br />

§ 95(1) makes debtor culpability the focal point, in some other respects the<br />

provisions are inconsistent with the debtor deterrence rationale. The following are<br />

some examples of the ambivalence in § 95.<br />

(1) Liability turns on proof of the debtor's intention and this is consistent with<br />

the debtor deterrence rationale. On the other hand, to the extent that courts<br />

determine the debtor's intention objectively, they treat the reference in § 95(1) to<br />

fraud as meaning constructive fraud. 87 This approach dilutes the key requirement of<br />

debtor culpability. The more readily the courts are prepared to infer the debtor's<br />

intention from the surrounding circumstances, the closer they move the regime<br />

82. Id. at 103.<br />

83. Norris, supra note 57, para 9.<br />

84. Id.; see also Re Advent Sales & Mktg. Corp. [20031, 46 C.B.R. (4th) 163, para. 12 (Can.); Re<br />

Chung [2006] CarswellOnt 975 (Can.); Coopers v. Lybrand Ltd. v. O'Brien Elec. Co. [1983], 47 C.B.R.<br />

(N.S.) 243 (Can.). Cf Krawchenko, supra note 9, para 25 (calling into question the requirement for proof<br />

of an imminent business crisis).<br />

85. See, e.g., Econ. Consulting Ltd. (Trustee of) v. Deloitte, Haskins & Sells Ltd. [1984] 53 C.B.R.<br />

(N.S.) 292 (Can.), affd [1985] 56 C.B.R. (N.S.) 60 (Can.); Re Kovalick [1973] 18 C.B.R. (N.S.) 69 (Can.);<br />

Davis v. Duncan Indus. Ltd., [1983] 45 C.B.R. (N.S.) 290 (Can.). Cf. Re Halls (Dalor Paper Co.) [1983] 45<br />

C.B.R. (N.S.) 81 (Can.) (evidence of threats and ultimatum regarding shipment of goods; presumption not<br />

overcome, but no reference by the court to non-relevance of pressure).<br />

86. Benallack, supra note 8.<br />

87. For applications of an objective approach, see, e.g., St Anne, supra note 9; Coast Wire Rope &<br />

Supply Ltd. (Trusee of) v. Trans Pacific Hardware [1999] 9 C.B.R. (4th) 255 (Can.); Principal Group Ltd.<br />

(Trustee of) v. Anderson [1994] 29 C.B.R. (3d) 216 (Can.) affd on other grounds, [1997], 46 C.B.R. (3d)<br />

101 (Can.).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 676 2006-2007


2007<br />

CANADIAN PREFERENCE LAW REFORM<br />

towards strict liability, where the goal is equal sharing, rather than debtor<br />

deterrence.m<br />

(2) Once the trustee has proved a preference in fact then, by virtue of § 95(2),<br />

the burden shifts to the creditor to prove that the debtor did not intend to give a<br />

preference. At first glance, this looks like no more than an evidentiary concession in<br />

the trustee's favour. On the other hand, some courts have taken a harder line than<br />

others in reaction to evidence the creditor leads. 9 The more difficult it is for<br />

creditors to rebut the presumption, the closer the evidentiary concession comes to a<br />

rule of law. Dilution of the debtor culpability element is inconsistent with the debtor<br />

deterrence rationale, but it might make sense in terms of either the creditor<br />

deterrence or the equal sharing rationales.<br />

(3) Section 95(2) states that evidence of pressure is not admissible to support<br />

the transaction. This provision is inconsistent with the debtor deterrence rationale<br />

because evidence of pressure negates the debtor's culpability, which is the key<br />

element from a debtor deterrence perspective." The provision would make sense if<br />

the creditor deterrence rationale applied, because evidence of pressure goes to the<br />

creditor's culpability, which is the key element from a creditor deterrence<br />

perspective. On the other hand, as previously mentioned, the express reference in §<br />

95(1) to the debtor's state of mind and the characterization of the debtor's conduct<br />

as fraudulent are inconsistent with the creditor deterrence rationale.<br />

(4) The creditor diligence defence compromises the rule that evidence of<br />

pressure is inadmissible to support the transaction, but the scope of the defence is<br />

uncertain as indicated by Re Hewston & Thornton and Re Norris. 9 ' In Re Hewston &<br />

Thornton, the court applied the defence robustly. This approach supports the debtor<br />

deterrence rationale but it is inconsistent with the express statutory provision<br />

excluding evidence of pressure. On the other hand, in Re Norris, 92 the court<br />

attempted to limit the defence to cases of extreme aggression on the creditor's part.<br />

This approach cuts both ways in policy terms. In so far as it limits the diligent<br />

creditor defence, it supports the creditor deterrence rationale. On the other hand, in<br />

so far as it ties the availability of the defence to the creditor's level of aggression, it is<br />

perverse from a creditor deterrence perspective because it means that the more<br />

culpable the creditor's actions, the more likely it is that the court will uphold the<br />

transaction. 93<br />

88. <strong>Law</strong> Reform Commission of British Columbia, supra note 33, at 122 ("In practice, intent-based<br />

schemes tend to produce unpredictable results. Personal views held by judges determine whether a<br />

disposition should be protected or set aside. The competing policies of treating creditors even-handedly<br />

and of protecting commercial transactions are given different weight by different judges"). Not all courts<br />

have adopted a purely objective view and in some instances the debtor's subjective belief has been taken<br />

into consideration. See, e.g., Re W. Slaunwhite & Sons Devs. Ltd., [1982] 45 C.B.R. (N.S.) 37 (Can.).<br />

Springman et al., supra note 52, at xx (analyzing four cases and finding "four different views on the nature<br />

of intention to prefer").<br />

89. Springman et al., supra note 52, at xx.<br />

90. See supra text accompanying note 67.<br />

91. See supra text accompanying notes 81-84.<br />

92. Norris, supra note 57, paras. 9-10.<br />

93. In other words, the creditor diligence exception creates a race among creditors, but this is the very<br />

outcome the bankruptcy laws were designed to prevent. See, e.g., W. R. Parker, FRAUDS ON CREDITORS<br />

AND ASSIGNMENTS FOR BENEFIT OF CREDITORS 109 (the common law, outside of bankruptcy "rewarded<br />

the diligent creditor").<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 677 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:661<br />

(5) Liability does not turn on the creditor's state of mind in receiving the<br />

preference. This is consistent with the debtor deterrence rationale. On the other<br />

hand, evidence of the creditor's state of mind is admissible as tending to show that<br />

the transaction was not in the ordinary course of business. The more weight a court<br />

attaches to such evidence, the further it pushes the regime in the direction of the<br />

creditor deterrence rationale.<br />

In summary, the current law lacks a clear policy foundation and in this sense it<br />

is indeterminate. Judicial glosses on the statutory text mean that the statute itself is<br />

not a complete statement of the law; this is a second sense in which the law is<br />

indeterminate. For example, there is no ordinary course of business defence in the<br />

statute, nor is there any reference to diligent creditors. However, the courts have<br />

imported both concepts, and there is a large body of cases, not all of them<br />

reconcilable, on the evidence a creditor must produce in order to establish the<br />

defences.<br />

A third source of indeterminacy is inconsistency in the way the courts exercise<br />

the discretion given to them by the judicially glossed statute. For example, in<br />

connection with the ordinary course of business defence, evidence is admissible to<br />

show that the debtor made the payment with a view to staying in business. However,<br />

the courts require proof that the debtor's hope of staying in business was a<br />

reasonable one, and the question of what amounts to a reasonable hope is one on<br />

which courts may differ. 94 As Wilson J. noted in Re Totem Printing Company Ltd.,<br />

many of the fraudulent preference decisions are "so divergent in thought as to offer<br />

a wide scope of choice to a court seeking a precedent. '<br />

There is a fourth sense in which the current law is indeterminate. Bankruptcy<br />

and Insolvency Act, §§ 95 and 96, are not a complete code. Provincial fraudulent<br />

preference laws apply concurrently. This means that if a transaction falls outside the<br />

review period §§ 95 and 96 specify, the trustee may still be able to attack it relying on<br />

the provincial laws instead. The concurrent operation of provincial law is open to<br />

criticism on at least two grounds: first, it potentially undermines the policies reflected<br />

in the federal provisions; and secondly, it raises the possibility of non-uniform case<br />

outcomes from province to province. 96 In the Senate Committee's words, the<br />

concurrent operation of provincial law results in "a lack of fairness, uniformity, and<br />

predictability." 91<br />

94. Compare St. Anne, supra note 9 (debtor's hope a reasonable one), with Canadawide Fruit, supra<br />

note 47 (debtor's hope an unreasonable one). Notwithstanding this objective approach, a number of courts<br />

have been willing to adopt a more subjective approach and have taken into account the debtor's bona fide<br />

belief even if that belief of continuing in business was "hopeless" or if the chances of saving the business<br />

were "very slim." E.g., Re Consolidated Seed Exports Ltd. [1986] 62 C.B.R. (N.S.) 156, para. 23 (Can.);<br />

see also Re AR Colquhoun & Son Ltd., [1936] 18 C.B.R. 124, para. 2 (Can.).<br />

95. [1960] 32 W.W.R. 143, para. 1 (Can.). The Newfoundland Supreme Court indicated that each case<br />

must stand on its own facts and "previous cases are not of much help, except for the principles of law as<br />

applied to the facts in them." In Re Lee & Ryan Ltd., [1966], 9 C.B.R. (N.S.) 281, para. 20 (Can.); see also<br />

Ronald C.C. Cuming, Canadian Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>: A Secured Creditor's Heaven, [1994] 24 CAN. BUS. L. J.<br />

17, 32 (1994) ("[Section 95 creates] a low level of predictability of outcome and the concomitant need to<br />

litigate almost every instance of an alleged preferential transfer.").<br />

96. See Dunlop, supra note 5.<br />

97. Senate Committee Report, supra note 3, at 122.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 678 2006-2007


2007<br />

CANADIAN PREFERENCE LAW REFORM<br />

IV.<br />

LAW REFORM INITIATIVES<br />

The Senate Committee in its 2003 Report recommended amendments to<br />

"ensure consistent and simplified rules for challenging fraudulent preferences." 9 In<br />

part, this recommendation was directed to the repeal of the provincial provisions<br />

with a view to establishing a "national standard" 9 for preference challenges.<br />

However, it is clear that the committee also had in mind amendments to §§ 95<br />

and 96 of the BIA themselves. The report touched on the question of whether the<br />

debtor's intent should continue to be the test, or whether it would be better to move<br />

to an effects-based test as other jurisdictions have done but it reached no conclusion,<br />

save for noting a concern expressed by the IIC and CAIRP Joint Task Force that<br />

"transactions made in good faith are not necessarily protected from an 'effectsbased'<br />

standard .... 100<br />

In the wake of the Senate Committee Report, a Joint Task Force Working<br />

Group formulated detailed recommendations for preference law reform, the central<br />

features of which are as follows:'<br />

(1) In the case of a non-arm's length transaction, the review period would be<br />

five years from the date of the original bankruptcy event or the initial application,<br />

while in the case of an arm's length transaction, the review period would be one<br />

year.<br />

(2) In the case of a non-arm's length transaction occurring within one year<br />

before the date of the initial bankruptcy event or the initial application, the trustee<br />

or monitor would need to prove only that the transaction amounted to a preference<br />

in fact.<br />

(3) In the case of a non-arm's length transaction occurring between one and<br />

five years before the date of the initial bankruptcy event or the initial application,<br />

the trustee or monitor would need to prove that: (a) the transaction amounted to a<br />

preference in fact; and (b) the debtor was insolvent at the time of the transaction or<br />

the transaction made the debtor insolvent.<br />

(4) In the case of an arm's length transaction, the trustee or monitor would<br />

need to prove that: (a) the transaction amounted to a preference in fact; and (b) the<br />

debtor intended to prefer the counterparty. There would be a rebuttable<br />

presumption of intention in the three months preceding the date of the initial<br />

bankruptcy event or the date of the initial application.<br />

(5) It would be a defence for the counterparty to prove that: (a) the debtor was<br />

solvent on the transaction date and not rendered insolvent by the transaction; or (b)<br />

the counterparty was entitled to receive the transfer in priority to other creditors.<br />

98. Id. at 123.<br />

99. Id. at 122.<br />

100. Id. The Insolvency Institute of Canada (IIC) and the Canadian Association of Insolvency and<br />

Restructuring Professionals (CAIRP) are the two peak bodies representing insolvency professionals in<br />

Canada. They formed a Joint Task Force in 2001for the purpose of making a detailed submission to the<br />

government on business insolvency law reform.<br />

101. IIC and CAIRP Joint Task Force on Business Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> Reform, Working Group on<br />

Preferences, Discussion Paper (2004) [hereinafter JTF Preferences Working Group Paper].<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 679 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:661<br />

Recently enacted amendments, not yet in force, replace § 96 of the BIA with<br />

the following provision:<br />

If the transfer, charge, payment obligation or judicial proceeding referred<br />

to in section 95 has the effect of giving a creditor who is not at arm's length<br />

a preference over other creditors, the review period referred to in<br />

subsection 95(1) is one year instead of three months.'9<br />

Under the previous version, the extended review period applied if the creditor<br />

was related to the debtor. Under the new version, the extended period applies if the<br />

creditor is not at arm's length, whether because it is related to the debtor or for some<br />

other reason. That is the extent of the change. The new provision does nothing to<br />

address the concerns outlined in Part III. However, it seems that the amendment<br />

was supposed to go further and that the real intention was to implement the JTF<br />

Working Group's Recommendation (3) by substituting an effects-based test for nonarm's<br />

length transactions. 1 1 3 Even if the new version is amended to reflect the actual<br />

intention, it still goes nowhere near addressing the concerns raised in Part III. There<br />

would still be the same indeterminacy problems as there are now. The only reason<br />

given in support of the proposed change was that it would "make it considerably<br />

easier for trustees to recover preferences from non-arm's length parties."' ' It is<br />

impossible to know whether this would be a good or bad thing in the absence of a<br />

benchmark for the desirable amount of recovery. 1 5 In any event, if the policy<br />

objective really is to facilitate preference recovery, the more logical response would<br />

be to move to a strict liability regime with no defences. It is also worth noting that<br />

the government's reason for the amendment conflicts with the JTF Working Group's<br />

main concern, which was to draft a set of provisions that did not unduly threaten the<br />

finality of transactions.<br />

For these reasons, it was a mistake for the government to cherry-pick from the<br />

JTF Working Group's model. This raises the question of whether the government<br />

should instead adopt the model in its entirety. There are several reasons why it<br />

should not do so. The main one is that the Working Group failed to articulate what<br />

it thought the governing policy considerations should be and this lack of a clear<br />

policy direction flows through into its recommendations. The JTF's stated concern<br />

was to "strike a balance between the ability of the debtor to conduct its affairs in the<br />

period prior to the commencement of insolvency proceedings and the ability of<br />

trustees, receivers and creditors to recover value where a transaction has given a<br />

preference contrary to the statute. 10 6 However, this statement fails to specify the<br />

purpose the preference laws are supposed to serve. The purpose might be one of<br />

102. Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act, supra note 50, as am. by R.S.C. 2005, c. 47, s.73.<br />

103. Email from Dave Stewart, Senior Project Leader, Office of the Superintendent of Bankruptcy, to<br />

Tony Duggan (Oct. 5, 2005).<br />

104. Id.<br />

105. In this connection, it is interesting to note that in Australia provisions were introduced to meet<br />

concerns that liquidators may have insufficient funds to bring preference actions. See Andrew Keay, An<br />

Exposition and Assessment of Unfair Preferences, 19 MELB. U. L. REv. 545, 577-79 (1994). However,<br />

recent amendments to the preference provisions in the United <strong>State</strong>s were motivated by concerns that<br />

creditors might not have the resources to defend preference claims. See Tabb, Brave New World, supra<br />

note 26, at 425-26.<br />

106. Insolvency Institute of Canada and Canadian Association of Insolvency and Restructuring<br />

Professionals, Report on Business Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> Reform, (2002), Commentary on Recommendation 66.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 680 2006-2007


2007<br />

CANADIAN PREFERENCE LAW REFORM<br />

debtor deterrence, creditor deterrence or equal sharing. As the discussion in Part 11<br />

indicates, a choice must be made because the purpose determines the shape of the<br />

legislation. An even more basic choice is whether to retain the preference laws at<br />

all. It is surprising that the JTF does not appear to have canvassed this option, given<br />

the importance it attached to the finality of transactions.<br />

The most distinctive feature of the JTF Working Group's model is that it<br />

requires proof of the debtor's intention to prefer, but only if the transaction is an<br />

arm's length one. In the case of a non-arm's length transaction, the test is an effectsbased<br />

one. No reasons were given in support of this approach. A possible<br />

explanation is that, if the transaction is a non-arm's length one, the debtor is more<br />

likely to have intended a preference. 7 However, this consideration at most supports<br />

a rebuttable presumption of intention." 8 It might be argued that an irrebuttable<br />

presumption saves litigation costs by forestalling inquiry into the debtor's state of<br />

mind. On the other hand, an irrebuttable presumption, like all bright-line rules, is<br />

potentially over-inclusive and the Working Group does not address the competing<br />

costs and benefits.<br />

A more fundamental concern is that, on this reading of the Working Group's<br />

model, the underlying rationale is debtor deterrence. However, the Working Group<br />

does not explain why it favours the debtor deterrence rationale over creditor<br />

deterrence or equal sharing. One challenge advocates of the debtor deterrence<br />

rationale face is to explain the absence of sanctions against the preference-giving<br />

debtor." 9 If the preference laws put the burden on the creditor, rather than the<br />

debtor, how can it be plausibly claimed that the objective is debtor deterrence?<br />

Another challenge is to address Schwartz's point that preference laws based on the<br />

debtor deterrence rationale are inefficient."" Advocates of the debtor deterrence<br />

rationale might claim that the objective is not efficiency, but fairness."' However,<br />

this would require a balancing of fairness gains against efficiency losses which the<br />

Working Group does not do.<br />

An alternative explanation of the Working Group's model is that the<br />

requirement for proof of the debtor's intention in the case of arm's length<br />

transactions was motivated by finality of transaction concerns, rather than debtor<br />

deterrence. If this is right, though, it takes us back to the starting point: assuming<br />

finality of transactions matters, and debtor deterrence is not the objective, why have<br />

preference laws at all? The creditor deterrence and equal sharing rationales are<br />

both possible explanations, but the Working Group does not say which of these it<br />

had in mind. If it was creditor deterrence, the model is deficient because there is no<br />

element of creditor culpability. If equal sharing, rather than creditor deterrence, was<br />

the goal there are efficiency concerns which should have been addressed.<br />

Furthermore, one way of reducing the finality of transactions concern is to shorten<br />

the review period: the shorter the review period, the lower the creditor's exposure."<br />

The Working Group does not explain why it did not take this step instead of, or<br />

perhaps as well as, relying on the proof of intention requirement as a controlling<br />

107. Australian <strong>Law</strong> Reform Commission, supra note 27, paras. 268-69.<br />

108. Id. paras. 272-73.<br />

109. See supra text accompanying notes 14-15.<br />

110. See supra text accompanying note 46.<br />

111. See supra text accompanying note 48.<br />

112. But not eliminating the finality of transactions concern. See supra text accompanying note 35.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 681 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:661<br />

factor. As it happens, the Working Group's model substantially lengthens the<br />

standard review period from the current three months to one year. By way of<br />

contrast, in the United <strong>State</strong>s, the standard review period is three months, and in<br />

Australia, England and New Zealand it is six months. The Working Group does not<br />

explain how the longer review period is reconcilable with its concern for finality of<br />

transactions.<br />

Professor Cuming has proposed an alternative model, based substantially on<br />

the United <strong>State</strong>s approach: an effects-based preference test coupled with various<br />

safe harbour provisions, the most important being an exception for "non-exceptional<br />

payments." 113 ' The following are non-exceptional payments: (1) the payment of a<br />

business debt under a running account arrangement; (2) the payment of a business<br />

debt if made within thirty-five days from the date the debtor received the property<br />

or service to which the debt relates; and (3) the payment of a loan where the period<br />

between the date the obligation was incurred and the date of the payment is not<br />

greater than thirty-five days." ' The non-exceptional payments exception replaces<br />

the United <strong>State</strong>s ordinary course of business defence, which Cuming rejected as<br />

being too imprecise.' 5<br />

There are grounds for this concern. For example, in 1993 New Zealand<br />

implemented an effects-based preference test coupled with an ordinary course of<br />

business exception, the immediate consequence of which was to substantially<br />

increase the volume and complexity of preference litigation. Among other things,<br />

the courts struggled with the questions of: (1) whether the ordinary course of<br />

business was to be assessed by reference to the debtor's industry at large or by<br />

reference to the debtor's relationship with the creditor in particular; and (2) what are<br />

the relevant variables for determining ordinariness."' The government is now in the<br />

process of repealing the ordinary course of business exception." 7<br />

In the United <strong>State</strong>s, the ordinary course provision has recently been amended<br />

to clarify the law in relation to Question (1)."' In Canada, where the courts have<br />

read an ordinary course of business defence into the statute, Question (2) is<br />

addressed in part by reference to whether the debtor made the payment in the<br />

expectation of being able to stay in business and, if so, whether the debtor's<br />

expectation was a reasonable one. The level of case-by-case inquiry involved makes<br />

litigation outcomes difficult to predict." 9<br />

113. Ronald C.C. Cuming, Unfair Preferences: Reformulation of Section 95 of the Bankruptcy and<br />

Insolvency Act (paper prepared for Industry Canada Corporate <strong>Law</strong> Policy Directorate, December 1997)<br />

[hereafter Unfair Preferences Report], subsequently published in abridged form as Ronald C.C. Cuming,<br />

Transfers at Undervalue and Preferences under the Bankruptcy and Insolvency Act: Rethinking Outdated<br />

Approaches, 37 CAN. Bus. L. J. 5 (2002) [hereinafter Cuming, Transfers].<br />

114. Unfair Preferences Report, supra note 113, recommendation 6.<br />

115. Cuming, Transfers, supra note 113, at.28-29.<br />

116. Thomas G.W. Telfer, Voidable Preference Reform: A New Zealand Perspective on Shifting<br />

Standards and Goalposts, 12 INT'L INSOLVENCY REv. 55, 75-80 (2003); New Zealand Ministry, Tier One<br />

Discussion, supra note 26, at 59 (citing uncertainty and costs as major reasons for repeal of the ordinary<br />

course of business exception).<br />

117. Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> Reform Bill, 2005 Bill [14-1] (N.Z.) 2006, cl. 478, amending the Companies Act<br />

1993. The proposal is to replace the ordinary course of business exception with a defence based on<br />

§588FG(2) of the Australian Corporations Act 2001. The Australian provision is discussed infra in text<br />

accompanying note 119.<br />

118. See supra text accompanying note 39.<br />

119. See supra text accompanying note 95.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 682 2006-2007


2007<br />

CANADIAN PREFERENCE LAW REFORM<br />

The Cuming model rests on the equal sharing rationale. Cuming says that a<br />

preferential transfer:<br />

"if left intact, frustrates implementation of the policy of bankruptcy<br />

legislation, equitable treatment of all creditors. The fact that the debtor<br />

intended or did not intend this result should not be relevant. The actual or<br />

presumed intentions of the debtor when making a preferential transfer are<br />

not important. What is important is the effect that such a transaction has<br />

on the position of creditors with claims in bankruptcy. What matters to<br />

them is that a central policy of bankruptcy law is not frustrated by a<br />

preferential payment or transfer which, by definition, results in material<br />

loss to them."' 2<br />

The preference provisions in the Australian Corporations Act of 2001 (Cth),<br />

which are based on recommendations the Australian <strong>Law</strong> Reform Commission<br />

made in its General Insolvency Inquiry Report, provide yet another model for<br />

reform. The Australian model incorporates an effects-based preference test coupled<br />

with a broadly stated good faith defence: it is a defence to a preference action if the<br />

creditor proves that: (1) it acted in good faith; (2) it had no grounds for suspecting<br />

that the debtor was insolvent or close to insolvency on the transaction date and a<br />

reasonable person in the creditor's circumstances would have had no reasonable<br />

grounds for so suspecting; and (3) the creditor provided valuable consideration or<br />

changed its position in reliance on the transaction.1 2 ' The Australian approach is<br />

different from the Cuming model in two important respects: (1) whereas the Cuming<br />

model rests on the equal sharing rationale, the goal of the Australian provisions is<br />

creditor deterrence as the good faith creditor defence makes clear; 2 2 and (2) the<br />

Cuming model's non-exceptional payments defence is rules-based, whereas the<br />

Australian good faith creditor defence is a standards-based one.<br />

Jackson claims that "preference law has never felt comfortable with any<br />

balance between a rule and a standard. During this century, the basic thrust of<br />

3<br />

preference law has been in the direction of a rule.', However, as he goes on to<br />

point out, in the United <strong>State</strong>s the commitment to rules is substantially eroded by<br />

the ordinary course of business exception."' The Australian approach is also<br />

standards-based, with the various costs that a standards-based approach entails, but<br />

it is more specific about what the creditor must prove and, for this reason, it is<br />

arguably better targeted than the ordinary course of business exception. 25 The<br />

Cuming model's rules-based approach avoids the case-by-case inquiry the Australian<br />

provisions involve and so it is more predictable. On the other hand, the thirty-five<br />

day cut-off point, like all bright line rules, is potentially both over- and underinclusive.<br />

To the extent that it is over-inclusive, it threatens the finality of<br />

120. Cuming, Transfers, supra note 113, at 23.<br />

121. Corporations Act 2001, c. 5 §588FG(2) (Austl.). Ironically, the course of United <strong>State</strong>s law<br />

reform has flowed in precisely the opposite direction: the Bankruptcy Act of 1898 introduced a<br />

requirement for proof of creditor intention, but the requirement was dropped in 1978 and replaced by the<br />

ordinary course exception. See Tabb, Rethinking Preferences, supra note 14, at 1007-15.<br />

122. See supra text accompanying note 29.<br />

123. Jackson, supra note 16, at 130-31.<br />

124. Id. at 131.<br />

125. Australian <strong>Law</strong> Reform Commission, supra note 27, at 272; cf. Keay, supra note 105, at 545.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 683 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:661<br />

transactions; to the extent that it is under-inclusive, it undermines the objective of<br />

26<br />

the preference laws.1<br />

The JTF Working Group made no reference to either the Cuming model or the<br />

Australian model. Perhaps the Working Group rejected the Cuming model because<br />

it disagreed with the equal sharing rationale or perhaps it thought that Cuming's<br />

non-exceptional payments exception was an insufficient safeguard for the finality of<br />

transactions. However, this is not explicitly provided by the Working Group.<br />

Likewise, the Working Group may have disliked the Australian model because it<br />

disagreed with the creditor deterrence rationale or, alternatively, because it thought<br />

that the good faith creditor defence was too imprecise. Again, though, these are<br />

simply speculations in the face of the Working Group's silence.<br />

V. CONCLUSION<br />

Preference law design implicates five key questions:<br />

(1) What is the objective: debtor deterrence, creditor deterrence or equality of<br />

distribution?<br />

(2) How much weight should the law give to competing concerns, such as<br />

finality of transactions and facilitating the provision of credit to financially distressed<br />

debtors?<br />

(3) What, if any, evidentiary concessions should the law make in favour of<br />

either the trustee or the creditor?<br />

(4) What form should the law take: bright-line rules, at the risk of over- and<br />

under-inclusiveness, or standards, at the risk of increased uncertainty?<br />

(5) What role, if any, is there for the concurrent application of provincial laws?<br />

Current Canadian preference law suffers from the failure to have systematically<br />

addressed any of these questions. The government's most recent reform initiatives<br />

are subject to the same criticism. The purpose of this paper has been to demonstrate<br />

that wholesale reform is necessary, and that tinkering of the kind the most recent<br />

reforms represent is at best insufficient and at worst counter-productive. There<br />

seems to be a general consensus on the need for reform, but there is as yet no<br />

consensus on how the questions listed above should be answered. Perhaps that is<br />

because until now policy makers and stakeholders have not given them sufficient<br />

thought. If this paper succeeds in raising the level of awareness about what the<br />

choices are, then it will have done its job. The choices themselves can then be left to<br />

others.<br />

126. Cuming's idea for the thirty-five-day cut-off point appears to derive from the United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978, Pub. L. No.95-598, §547 (c)(2), which limited the ordinary course of<br />

business defence to transfers made not later than forty-five days after the debt was incurred. The1984<br />

reforms took out the forty-five-day cut-off point. See Tabb, Rethinking Preferences, supra note 14, at<br />

1014-16. Jackson favours its reintroduction, subject to making the time run from the date the debt was first<br />

due, rather than when it was incurred. Jackson, supra note 16, at 131.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 684 2006-2007


Recent International Developments in the <strong>Law</strong><br />

of Negotiable Instruments and Payment and<br />

Settlement Systems<br />

BENJAMIN GEVA*<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. O V E R V IEW ........................................................................................................... 685<br />

II, THE CHECK PAYMENT AS AN ELECTRONIC FUNDS TRANSFER ..................... 687<br />

A . In trod uction ................................................................................................. 687<br />

B. The "Electronic Check": Check as an EFT Authorization ..................... 689<br />

C. A Rem otely Created Check ........................................................................ 690<br />

D . E lectronic P resentm ent ............................................................................... 691<br />

E . E lectronic N egotiation ................................................................................ 694<br />

III. PAYMENT CARDS -THE PAYROLL CARD AS AN ACCESS DEVICE ............... 699<br />

IV.<br />

SECURITIES TRANSFERS IN THE INDIRECT HOLDING SYSTEM -LAW<br />

REFORM IN CANADA IN THE FOOTSTEPS OF UCC ARTICLE 8 ....................... 705<br />

V. EU PROPOSED LEGAL FRAMEWORK FOR A SINGLE PAYMENT MARKET.... 712<br />

A . Introduction ................................................................................................. 712<br />

B. Licensing of Non-Bank Payment Service Providers ................................ 714<br />

C. Transparency of Conditions for Payment Services .................................. 716<br />

D. Rights and Obligations of Users and Providers of Payment Services .... 718<br />

E . F inal R em arks .............................................................................................. 725<br />

V I. C O N C LU SIO N ....................................................................................................... 725<br />

I. OVERVIEW<br />

This paper surveys four recent major developments worldwide in the areas of<br />

negotiable instruments and payment and settlement systems. Only private or<br />

LL M, SJD, Harvard <strong>Law</strong> School; Professor of <strong>Law</strong>, Osgoode Hall <strong>Law</strong> School York University,<br />

Toronto, Canada [2005-2006: Adjunct Professor and Visiting Scholar, Northwestern University School of<br />

<strong>Law</strong>, Chicago, IL].<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 685 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

commercial law aspects are considered; regulatory and public law issues are outside<br />

the scope of the present discussion. Topics covered are checks, payment cards,<br />

securities transfers, and payment transactions. A common theme is the adaptation<br />

by statute of the law to the world of electronic banking as it keeps evolving.<br />

The first development, outlined in Part II, is concerned with the ongoing<br />

transformation of the check payment into an electronic funds transfer. The check<br />

has been characterized as the paper-based payment system par excellence. Recently,<br />

this view has been eroded in several ways. Principal developments outlined in this<br />

paper consist of the "electronic check" in the United <strong>State</strong>s; the remotely created<br />

check in the United <strong>State</strong>s and Canada; electronic presentment in the United <strong>State</strong>s,<br />

UK, recent law reform in Sri Lanka and a proposal in Canada; and "electronic<br />

negotiation" under "Check 21 Act" in the United <strong>State</strong>s. A procedure in which the<br />

physical movement of checks is curtailed or eliminated, being replaced, in whole or<br />

in part, by electronic transmission of information is called "check truncation." To a<br />

large extent, check truncation reflects a partial conversion of the check collection<br />

process to an electronic funds transfer.<br />

The second development, covered by Part III, is the evolving legal framework<br />

applicable to payment cards. A fundamental distinction has been known to exist<br />

between access and stored-value payment cards. The recent emergence in the<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s of payroll, remittance and gift cards has required their classification in<br />

that framework. A recent amendment in the United <strong>State</strong>s placed the payroll card<br />

under Regulation E governing access device. Yet earlier parameters established by<br />

the Federal Reserve Board, to which no reference was made in connection with the<br />

recent amendment, but which are followed in the literature and banking parlance,<br />

would have suggested the payroll card is a stored-value card. With the view of<br />

eliminating future confusion, Part III endeavors to reconstruct these earlier<br />

parameters, to clarify the distinction between access and stored-value cards, and thus<br />

to facilitate an appropriate framework for future developments. Specifically, Part III<br />

is designed to justify the treatment of the payroll card as an access device as<br />

conceptually sound.<br />

The third development, outlined in Part IV, is the acceleration in the<br />

modernization of the law of securities transfers. Recent Canadian legislation<br />

modeled on Article 8 of the American Uniform Commercial Code, passed in May<br />

2006, provides for a comprehensive framework dealing with all modes of securities<br />

holdings and transfers. Particularly, it covers the indirect-tier holding, namely, the<br />

transfer and pledge of "security entitlements" credited and debited to "securities<br />

accounts" maintained with "securities intermediaries" such as brokerage firms which<br />

in turn maintain securities accounts with a Central Depositary of Securities (CDS).<br />

The fourth development, outlined in Part V, is the European march towards a<br />

Pan-European common payment law. With the view of creating a Single Payment<br />

Market where improved economies of scale and competition would help to reduce<br />

cost of the payment system, the Commission of the European Communities<br />

proposed in December 2005 to establish a common framework for the Community<br />

payments market creating the conditions for integration and rationalisation of<br />

national payment systems. Focusing on electronic payments, the Commission made<br />

a proposal for a Directive on payment services in the internal market, designed to<br />

provide for a harmonised legal framework. Intended to leave maximum room for<br />

self-regulation of industry, the Proposed Directive purports to harmonise only what<br />

is necessary to overcome legal barriers to a Single Euro Payment Area (SEPA).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 686 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 687<br />

II.<br />

THE CHECK PAYMENT AS AN ELECTRONIC FUNDS TRANSFER'<br />

A. Introduction<br />

By its nature, a check is an order to pay given by a customer to a bank with<br />

which the customer maintains an account. It is a paper instrument, embodying an<br />

unconditional order in writing, signed by a drawer, instructing a drawee bank to<br />

make payment to or to the order of a designated payee, or to the bearer. 2 The<br />

person to whom a check is payable and who is in possession of the check is its<br />

holder. 3 A check is issued when the drawer delivers it to the first holder. 4 Once<br />

issued, a check may circulate from hand to hand, namely be negotiated, by delivery<br />

from one holder to another; in the case of a check payable to order, negotiation<br />

consists of delivery accompanied by the signature of the holder, called<br />

"indorsement." ' To obtain payment, the last holder is to have the check physically<br />

presented to the drawee bank. 6<br />

Typically, a holder will not present the check to the drawee bank in person.<br />

Rather, the holder is likely to have the check deposited with and collected by a<br />

depositary bank, with which the holder maintains an account. The depositary bank<br />

will then either present the check directly to the drawee bank, or negotiate it to an<br />

intermediary bank. There may be one or more negotiations to one or more<br />

intermediary banks. The last intermediary bank will present the check for payment<br />

to the drawee. In that process, all banks other than the drawee, namely the<br />

depositary bank and each intermediary bank, are collecting banks, the drawee bank<br />

is the payor bank, and the collecting bank that presents the check for payment to the<br />

drawee bank is the presenting bank.'<br />

The normal process thus entails a series of physical deliveries of the piece of<br />

paper embodying the check. First, the check is physically issued by the drawer to the<br />

first holder. Second, there may be one or more physical negotiations outside the<br />

banking system. Third, there is the physical delivery of the check by the holder to<br />

the depositary bank. Fourth, there may be one or more deliveries of the check to<br />

intermediary bank(s). Fifth, the process concludes with a physical presentment of<br />

the check to the drawee. Following payment, there is possibly a sixth and postconcluding<br />

stage, in which the cancelled check is delivered by the payor bank to the<br />

drawer, together with the periodic statement containing it. Conversely, where the<br />

drawee dishonors the check, the check is returned in a reversed itinerary.<br />

1. See generally BENJAMIN GEVA, THE LAW OF ELECTRONIC FUNDS TRANSFERS § 1.07 (1992-2006)<br />

[hereinafter GEVA, LAW OF EFT].<br />

2. U.C.C. § 3-104(f) (2006); Bills of Exchange Act, R.S.C., ch. B-4, §§ 165(1), 17(1) (1985) (Can.).<br />

Canadian Bills of Exchange Act provisions cited in footnotes 2-6 and 12 have parallels in all statutes<br />

modeled on the England's Bills of Exchange Act. Bills of Exchange Act, 1882, 45 & 46 Vict., c. 61 (Eng.).<br />

3. U.C.C. § 1-201(b)(21)(B); Bills of Exchange Act, R.S.C., ch. B-4, § 2.<br />

4. U.C.C. § 3-105; Bills of Exchange Act, R.S.C., ch. B-4, § 2.<br />

5. U.C.C. §§ 3-201, -204; Bills of Exchange Act, R.S.C., ch. B-4, §§ 2, 59 (substituting "endorsement"<br />

for "indorsement").<br />

6. A point implied, though not specifically provided for, in the U.C.C., speaking of the exhibition of<br />

the check to, and its handling by, the drawee. U.C.C. § 3-501(b)(2). However, the Bills of Exchange Act is<br />

straightforward on this point. Bills of Exchange Act, R.S.C., ch. B-4, § 84(3).<br />

7. See U.C.C. §§ 4-104 to -105 (providing applicable definitions).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 687 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

Modern law facilitates variations by agreement; as may be necessary it may<br />

further provide for the position of third parties under the law of checks where such<br />

variations have been agreed. First, a check may be given as a source of information<br />

to be used to initiate a one-time electronic fund transfer, in which case it is often<br />

described as an "electronic check." Second, a check may be remotely created. Third,<br />

a check may be negotiated to a collecting bank, whether by its customer the holder,<br />

or another collecting bank, by means of electronic transmission. Fourth, a check<br />

may be presented for payment electronically. At the same time, no practice of<br />

electronic negotiation to non-banks has developed so that no provision for such<br />

electronic transmission has been made.<br />

As a source of information, a check may be given to the payee with the<br />

authority to convert it to an electronic image. A remotely created check is drawn by<br />

the payee, as an agent of the drawer, on the basis of information provided by the<br />

drawer to the payee, typically, over the telephone. Both electronic negotiation and<br />

presentment consist of the transmission of an electronic image instead of the physical<br />

transfer of the paper check. In the United <strong>State</strong>s, inter-bank transmission of check<br />

images takes place over dedicated telecommunication channels, provided by both<br />

Federal Reserve Banks, 8 and the private sector9<br />

All four procedures involve check truncation, namely a procedure in which the<br />

"physical movement of [checks] is curtailed or eliminated, being replaced, in whole<br />

or in part, by electronic [transmission of information]."' ' Inasmuch as it constitutes<br />

the transmission of payment information other than by the delivery of paper check,<br />

each of the four procedures results in an electronic funds transfer for the pertinent<br />

stage of the check transaction. The ensuing discussion will outline proposed and<br />

existing legislative and regulatory frameworks to govern all four procedures. It will<br />

commence with the "electronic check," discuss the remotely created check, move on<br />

to the electronic presentment, and conclude with the electronic negotiation, the<br />

latter being the most elaborate scheme.<br />

To a large extent, these variations reflect a partial conversion of the check<br />

collection process to an electronic funds transfer. To that end, one may roughly<br />

describe the process as a whole as the "dematerialization" of the check, or perhaps<br />

better, as its immobilization," namely the substitution of any stage in its physical<br />

transfer, by the transmission of its information or electronic image. By analogy then,<br />

8. See FEDERAL RESERVE BANKS, GUIDE TO CONNECTIVITY OPTIONS FOR FEDFORWARDRM ,<br />

FEDRETURN", AND FEDRECEPTRM SERVICES (VERSION 2) (2005), available at<br />

http://www.frbservices.org/Retail/pdf/C21ConnectivityGuide.pdf.<br />

9. A major player is SVPCO, which is the Check and Electronic Clearing Service of The Clearing<br />

House Payments Company. SVPCO, About Us, http://www.svpco.com/about/000162f.php (last visited<br />

May 10, 2007). The service covers electronic check presentment and check imaging. Id. Its "SVPCO<br />

Image Payments Network is an industry utility for all financial institutions [which] lets each participant<br />

transmit images directly to other participants." SVPCO Image Payments Network,<br />

http://www.svpco.com/payment-services/check-image-exchange/000093.php (last visited May 10, 2007).<br />

"SVPCO Image Payments Network facilitates "peer-to-peer" exchanges without going through a central<br />

processing facility." Id.<br />

10. COMM. ON PAYMENT & SETTLEMENT SYS., BANK FOR INT'L SETTLEMENTS, A GLOSSARY OF<br />

TERMS USED IN PAYMENTS AND SETTLEMENT SYSTEMS 50 (2003), available at<br />

http://www.bis.org/publ/cpss0Ob.pdf (stating one example of the definition of "truncation).<br />

11. These are terms borrowed from the law of securities transfers, which is discussed in Part III of this<br />

Paper. For the use of "dematerialization" in the present context, I am obliged to Bradley Crawford. My<br />

own preference to "immobilization" stems from the fact that as in the immobilization of securities, the<br />

process involves the conversion and not elimination of paper.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 688 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 689<br />

the entire transformation of the paper-based payment system into an electronic<br />

funds transfer may be viewed as the "decertification" of the check. In the process,<br />

the law of checks is being transformed into the law of electronic funds transfers. The<br />

ensuing discussion covers developments in the legal framework for each of the four<br />

variations outlined above; it does not go as far as to introduce an overall theory<br />

encompassing the entire transformation process.<br />

B. The "Electronic Check": Check as an EFT Authorization<br />

On occasion, a check may not be "issued" so as to give the payee rights thereon<br />

to enforce payment in discharge of the underlying obligation; 2 rather, contrary to<br />

the usual presumption of conditional payment by check, 3 a check may be given to<br />

the payee merely as a source of information to be used to initiate a one-time<br />

electronic fund transfer from the drawer's account in payment of the obligation. The<br />

check is then used as a source document to collect the drawer's routing number,<br />

account number, check's serial number and the sum payable. In effect, the check is<br />

thus converted to a single debit entry which is then input to the ACH (Automated<br />

Clearing House) Network. This arrangement is particularly common in consumer<br />

transactions. Where the check is mailed to the payee-merchant, the check is<br />

converted to an ARC-Accounts Receivables Entry. Where the check is given to<br />

the payee-merchant in a face-to-face transaction the check is converted to a POP-<br />

Point-of-Purchase Entry. Once converted, the check itself is voided; in a face-to-face<br />

transaction it is typically returned to the consumer-drawer. 14<br />

The electronic image created by the merchant, usually at the point-of-sale, is<br />

often colloquially referred to as an "electronic check." In fact this is a misnomer;<br />

what is generated on the basis of the information derived from the check is not a<br />

"check" but rather an ACH debit entry. Payment is then not governed by UCC<br />

Articles 3 and 4, but rather is brought into the ambit of Regulation E, issued by the<br />

Federal Reserve Board, governing consumer electronic fund transfers." 9 Regulation<br />

E requires the merchant to "provide a notice that the transaction will or may be<br />

processed as an electronic fund transfer, and obtain a consumer's authorization for<br />

each transfer."'"<br />

12. See U.C.C. § 3-105(a) (2006) (defining "Issue" as "the first delivery of an instrument by the maker<br />

or drawer, whether to a holder or nonholder, for the purpose of giving rights on the instrument to any<br />

person."); Bills of Exchange Act, R.S.C., ch. B-4, § 2 (1985) (Can.) (to a similar effect, defining "issue" as<br />

the first delivery to a holder).<br />

13. See U.C.C. § 3-310(b) (stating the presumption which states that "[u]nless otherwise agreed.,. if.<br />

.. an uncertified check is taken for an obligation, the obligation is suspended ... until dishonor of the<br />

check or until [the check] is paid or certified."); In re Charge Card Services Ltd., [1988] 3 W.L.R. 764 (CA)<br />

(Eng.) (discussing the conditional payment presumption in the common law).<br />

14. See NACHA, ACH Operating Rules, §§ 3.7-3.8 (2007). For bulk electronic payments processed<br />

through the ACH (Automated Clearing House) Network and for NACHA (National Automated Clearing<br />

House Association), as well as for NACHA Operating Rules and Guidelines, see GEVA, LAW OF EFr,<br />

supra note 1, ch. 5.<br />

15. Regulation E excludes from the term "electronic fund transfers" .[any transfer of funds<br />

originated by check ...." 12 C.F.R. § 205.3(c)(1) (2006). However, the theory of the check conversion is<br />

that the transfer is initiated by the converted debit entry, rather than the check, that has been used as a<br />

mere source of information. Id. § 205.3(b)(2).<br />

16. Id. § 205.3(b)(2) (codifying 71 Fed. Reg. 1638 (Jan. 10, 2006)). Briefly stated, the underlying<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 689 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

It should, however, be pointed out that in principle there is nothing to preclude<br />

the issue of a paper check by a drawer-buyer of goods or services in payment or<br />

discharge of the obligation to the payee-merchant 7 and its subsequent electronic<br />

presentment to the drawee bank by the merchant through the depositary bank. The<br />

banking operation involved may not be different than that of the current "electronic<br />

check" collection procedure as outlined above; and yet, it would be governed by the<br />

law of checks," 8 in which case it is hard to rationalize any disclosure or authorization<br />

requirement as under Regulation E. Indeed, the check collection is a regular debit<br />

transfer; the "electronic check" collection scenario lends further support to the view<br />

that a separate law to govern check collection is outdated.<br />

C. A Remotely Created Check<br />

A remotely created check is typically generated when the drawer authorizes the<br />

payee to produce a check drawn on the drawer's account. The drawer does not sign<br />

the check, which generally bears either the drawer's printed or typed name or a<br />

statement as to the issue of the check under the drawer's authority. The check is<br />

deposited by the payee at a depositary bank, under an agreement under which the<br />

payee warrants the drawer's authority. Authorization to the payee is typically given<br />

over the telephone; the remotely created check is thus a useful mechanism to make a<br />

one-shot "last minute" and yet a timely payment.<br />

The issue or creation of the remotely created check is a matter between the<br />

drawer and the payee. Its deposit is a matter to be agreed between the payee and<br />

the depositary bank. Obviously however, a customer will not authorize the drawee<br />

to honor any remotely created check that merely purports to emanate under that<br />

customer's authority; the customer is not to be charged with checks not actually<br />

issued under that customer's authority. Yet, inasmuch as remotely created checks do<br />

not bear signatures or other ready means to verify authority, they are vulnerable to<br />

fraud. In the absence of specific protection measures discussed immediately below, a<br />

drawee bank that pays a remotely created check thus pays it at its peril, bearing the<br />

risk of unauthorized payment out of a customer's account.<br />

Regulatory and legal response providing protection to the drawee bank against<br />

the fraud risk dramatically varies between Canada and the United <strong>State</strong>s. In<br />

Canada, the Canadian Payments Association (CPA)" 9 prohibits the clearing of<br />

remotely created checks, or "tele-cheques" in the Canadian terminology. 20 In the<br />

theory of the requirement is that conversion may change the consumer's position, insofar as payment is<br />

likely to be speedier and the cancelled check will not prove payment.<br />

17. As will be the normal procedure. See supra note 13 and accompanying text.<br />

18. See discussion infra Part II.D-E (electronic presentment and negotiation under the law of checks).<br />

19. Canadian Payments Act, R.S.C., ch. C-21 (1985), amended by 2001 S.C., ch. 9 (Can.) (establishing<br />

the Canadian Payments Association (CPA)). The CPA's membership consists of financial institutions and<br />

is mandated to "establish and operate national systems for the clearing and settlement of payments and<br />

other arrangements for the making or exchange of payments .. " Id. § 5(1)(a). Its Board may make rules<br />

"respecting payment items acceptable for exchange, clearing or settlement .. " Id. § 19(1)(a). CPA Rule<br />

Al identifies payment items that are eligible for clearing. CPA, Rule Al-General Rules Pertaining to Items<br />

Acceptable for Exchange, for the Purpose of Clearing and Settlement (2004), available at<br />

http://www.cdnpay.ca/rules/pdfsrules/rule-al.pdf.<br />

20. In fact, there is no explicit prohibition in a specific Rule. Rather, it is the CPA's Policy <strong>State</strong>ment<br />

that effectively prohibits tele-cheques. CPA Policy <strong>State</strong>ment, Prohibition of Tele-cheques in the Clearing<br />

& Settlement System (June 3, 2003), available at http://www.cdnpay.ca/news/tele.asp. Rule A4 outlines the<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 690 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 691<br />

absence of a pre-existing written and signed authorization by the drawer, fraud, due<br />

to the inability of the drawee bank to verify the authority of its customer, is cited as<br />

the "key risk associated with a tele-cheque." 2 In short, protection is afforded to the<br />

drawee bank in the form of a ban on the practice.<br />

In contrast, the remotely created check is an accepted practice in the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s. To protect the payor bank from the fraud risk, and still facilitate the use of<br />

the remotely created check, that otherwise may have not been honored by that bank,<br />

both the UCC 22 and Regulation CC 23 create transfer and presentment warranties.<br />

Thereunder, the depositary bank warrants that the remotely created check, which it<br />

is transferring or presenting, is authorized by the person on whose account the check<br />

is drawn. Loss caused by a check issued without proper authority of the person on<br />

whose account the check purports to be drawn thus falls on the depositary bank,<br />

which is the bank that dealt directly with the payee, who is the party that created the<br />

check. " It is then up to that bank to shift by contract the risk to its customer, the<br />

payee, from whom the bank accepted the check for collection.<br />

D. Electronic Presentment<br />

Electronic presentment is provided for by UCC Section 4-110. Thereunder, the<br />

presentment of a check may be made pursuant to an agreement for presentment.<br />

"Agreement for electronic presentment" could be in the form of an agreement,<br />

clearing-house rule, or Federal Reserve regulation or operating circular." The<br />

agreement is to provide "that presentment ... may be made by the transmission of<br />

an image of [a check] or information describing [it] . . .rather than delivery of the<br />

[check] itself." 6 The transmission of the image or information constitutes a<br />

"presentment notice"; its receipt is the actual presentment. Other elements that may<br />

be covered by the agreement for electronic presentment are "procedures governing<br />

retention, . . . payment, dishonor and other matters . . .., Arguably, return<br />

return time-frame for tele-cheques, which "may be returned for the reason 'Not Eligible for Clearing' up to<br />

and including 90 days after being received by the Drawee." CPA, Rule A4-Returned and Redirected Items<br />

§ 6(g) (2005), available at http://www.cdnpay.ca/rules/pdfs-rules/rule-a4.pdf.<br />

21. CPA Policy <strong>State</strong>ment, supra note 20.<br />

22. U.C.C. §§ 3-416(a)(6), 3-417(a)(4), 4-207(a)(6), 4-208(a)(4) (2006).<br />

23. 12 C.F.R. §§ 229.2(fff), 229.34(d) (2006) (having consequential amendments in sections 210.5,<br />

210.6, 210.9). Federal law purports to mirror the aforesaid U.C.C. provisions and is designed to rectify the<br />

lack of their universal adoption throughout the entire country.<br />

24. See Collection of Checks and Other Items by Federal Reserve Banks and Funds Transfers<br />

Through Fedwire and Availability of Funds and Collection of Checks, 70 Fed. Reg. 71,218 (Nov. 28, 2005)<br />

(codified at 12 CFR pts. 210 & 229; 70 Fed. Reg. 10,509 (March 4, 2005) (codified at 12 C.F.R. pts. 210 &<br />

229); Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Request for Comment on Proposed Rule Governing Remotely<br />

Created Checks - Regulation CC, Circular No. 11688 (Mar. 8, 2005), available at<br />

http://www.newyorkfed.org/banking/circulars/11688.html.<br />

25. See, e.g., Regulation J, 12 C.F.R. § 210.2 (defining "item" in section 210.2(i) to include "electronic<br />

item," such as an "electronic image" of a check or any other paper item); see also Federal Reserve Bank,<br />

Operating Circular No. 3: Collection of Cash Items and Returned Checks § 5 & apps. E, E-E3 (July 1,<br />

2004), available at http://www.frbservices.org/OperatingCirculars/pdf/Oc3.pdf (stating that electronic access<br />

to Reserve Bank's Services is governed by Section 5 and Appendices E (MICR Presentment Services), El<br />

(Truncation Service), E2 (MICR Presentment Plus Service), and E3 (Basic MICR Presentment Service)).<br />

26 U.C.C. § 4-110.<br />

27 Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 691 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

procedures fall in the ambit of the agreement. An interbank voluntary agreement<br />

may be either bilateral or multilateral. 8 In any event, per the language quoted<br />

above, "agreement for electronic presentment" under Section 4-110 may for<br />

example be constituted by means of a regulation or a circular issued by the Federal<br />

Reserve and thus may not be entirely consensual; this is however in line with UCC<br />

Section 4-103(b) under which "Federal Reserve regulations and operating circulars,<br />

clearing-house rules, and the like have the effect of agreements . . ., whether or not<br />

specifically assented to by all parties interested in items handled." '2 9<br />

At the same time, the scheme that was introduced in England in 1996 appears<br />

to have stronger compulsory features. Under Section 74B of the Bills of Exchange<br />

Act, 3° "a banker may present a cheque for payment to the banker on whom it is<br />

drawn by notifying him of its essential features by electronic means or otherwise,<br />

instead of by presenting the cheque itself."'" However, in the final analysis, the<br />

option is not entirely in the hands of the presenting bank:<br />

if, before the close of business on the next business day following<br />

presentment of a cheque under this section, the banker on whom the<br />

cheque is drawn requests the banker by whom the cheque was presented<br />

to present the cheque itself-(a) the presentment under this section shall<br />

be disregarded, and (b) this section shall not apply in relation to the<br />

subsequent presentment of the cheque. 32<br />

The obligations of a banker making and receiving an electronic presentment that has<br />

not been timely rejected are stated to "be subject to the same duties in relation to<br />

the collection and payment of the cheque as if the cheque itself had been presented<br />

for payment," except that "[an electronic] presentment need not be made at the<br />

proper place or at a reasonable hour on a business day." 33<br />

Along similar lines, a more detailed scheme was recently adopted in Sri<br />

Lanka. 3 ' It goes further in containing the following elements. First, it specifically<br />

28. One such multilateral agreement is under the rules of the check truncation program of NACHA<br />

for electronic images of truncated checks input to the ACH Network. Check truncated items input to the<br />

ACH Network are TRC/TRX entries referred to as a category of Payment Applications in NACHA<br />

Operating Guidelines (as well as in the ACH Primer preceding NACHA Operating Rules), and are<br />

governed by the NACHA Operating Rules. NACHA, ACH Operating Rules, supra note 14, § 1(2)(c);<br />

NACHA, A CH Rules Primer, § (c)(3); NACHA, Operating Rules of the National Association for Check<br />

Safekeeping art. 10 (2007). For bulk electronic payments processed through the ACH Network and for<br />

NACHA, as well as for NACHA Operating Rules and Guidelines, see GEVA, LAW OF EFT, supra note 1,<br />

ch. 5.<br />

29 U.C.C. § 4-103(b).<br />

30. Bills of Exchange Act, 1882, 45 & 46 Vict., c. 61, § 74B (Eng.); Deregulation (Bills of Exchange)<br />

Order, 1996, S.I. 1996/2993, art. 4(1).<br />

31. Bills of Exchange Act, 1882, 45 & 46 Vict., c. 61, § 74B (Eng.). "Essential features" are defined to<br />

consist of "(a) the serial number of the cheque, (b) the code which identifies the banker on whom the<br />

cheque is drawn, (c) the account number of the drawer of the cheque, and (d) the amount of the cheque is<br />

entered by the drawer of the cheque." Id. § 74B(6).<br />

32. Id. § 74B(3).<br />

33. Id. §§ 74B(2), (5) (as otherwise required under section 45(3)). Also, physical exhibition of the<br />

check, otherwise required for a lawful presentment under section 52(4), is dispensed with under section<br />

74C. Id. §§ 52(4), 74C.<br />

34. Payment and Settlement Systems Act, No. 28 of 2005, §§ 33-37 (Sri Lanka), available at<br />

http://www.cbsl.gov.lk/pics-ndocs/09I r/_docs/acts/Paymt-&-setmt-sys-act.pdf. Under section 36(3):<br />

"The provisions of [Part II1] shall, in so far as it is possible be read and construed as one with the Bills of<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 692 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 693<br />

requires the electronic presentment of the check to consist of the transmission of its<br />

"image ... along with ... stipulated electronic payment information ..... .Second,<br />

it limits the right to decline electronic presentment and request a physical one only in<br />

the case of technical failure. 36 Third, it provides for an "image return document,"<br />

stated to "be deemed to be the cheque to which it relates," 37 to be returned to the<br />

presenting bank in the case of the dishonor of the check. Fourth, it provides for<br />

warranties and indemnities made by the banker making an electronic presentment as<br />

well as the banker issuing an image return document. 3 Finally, and subject to "rules,<br />

directions or instructions issued by the Central Bank," the scheme authorizes its<br />

implementation by means of interbank agreements, "including those in the form of<br />

clearing house rules." 3 9<br />

Electronic check presentment is now on the legislative agenda in Canada. A<br />

proposal of the Canadian Payments Association (CPA)" to amend the Bills of<br />

Exchange Act 4 follows the English precedent 2 and further clarifies 43 that electronic<br />

Exchange Ordinance (Chapter 82)." Id. § 36(3).<br />

35. Id. § 33(1). In comparison, the English provision requires the notification of the essential features<br />

of the check "by electronic means or otherwise ...." Bills of Exchange Act, 1882, 45 & 46 Vict, c. 61, §<br />

74B (Eng.). On this point, in Sri Lanka, similarly as in the UK, the stipulated information consists of the<br />

serial number of the check, the code identification of the presenting bank, the drawer's account number,<br />

the amount of the check, as well as (in departure from the English provision) "any other matter as may<br />

from time to time be prescribed by regulation." Payment and Settlement Systems Act, No. 28 of 2005, §<br />

33(8) (Sri Lanka).<br />

36. Payment and Settlement Systems Act, No. 28 of 2005, §§ 33(3), (5) (Sri Lanka).<br />

37. Id. § 34(2).<br />

38. Id. § 35. Briefly stated, the presenting banker's warranties relate to the accuracy of the image and<br />

the information. Id. § 35(1). "He shall also indemnify the drawer against any loss incurred due to the<br />

[electronic] presentment ...." Id. Loss is likely to be rare, as for example where the original check,<br />

needed as a piece of evidence to establish forgery that cannot be proved otherwise, cannot be retrieved.<br />

The issuer of an image return document warrants the accuracy of the document "and shall also indemnify<br />

the drawer against any loss in the event of the cheque itself being paid or sued on." Id. § 35(2). All<br />

warranties and indemnities are in favor of the drawee bank, its customer, the holder who delivered the<br />

check for collection, and any other endorser. Id. § 35(3). The person stated to be the drawer may recover<br />

directly from the drawee banker, who is then subrogated to the claim against the warrantor or the person<br />

liable on the indemnity obligation. Id. § 35(4).<br />

39. Payment and Settlement Systems Act, No. 28 of 2005, § 37 (Sri Lanka). Unlike under the U.C.C.,<br />

interbank agreements are stated to be "binding [only] between the parties thereto." Id. Conversely, legal<br />

pronouncements issued by the Central Bank "are deemed to bind and benefit [all] parties liable on and<br />

entitled to enforce a cheque .... Id.<br />

40. See CPA, Submission to the Department of Finance in Response to the Call for Comments on "An<br />

Effective and Efficient Legislative Framework for the Canadian Financial Services Sector" (May 26, 2005)<br />

[hereinafter CPA, Submission to the Department of Finance], available at<br />

http://www.cdnpay.ca/publications/pdfs-publications/2006%2OFinancial%2OLegislative%2Review.pdf.<br />

For the CPA and its mandate, see supra note 19.<br />

41. Bills of Exchange Act, R.S.C., ch. B-4 (1985) (Can.).<br />

42. For an effective electronic presentment under proposed section 165.1(3),<br />

"the essential features of a cheque must be transmitted in a form that is intelligible or easily<br />

decipherable by the drawee bank and, at a minimum, must identify the sum ordered to be paid,<br />

the serial number of the cheque, the account against which it is drawn, and the code or number<br />

that identifies the bank on the which the cheque is drawn."<br />

Canadian Bankers Ass'n., The 2006 Financial Services Legislation Review: Improving the Legislative<br />

Framework for Canadian Consumers, app. C (June 1, 2005), available at<br />

http://www.cba.ca/en/content/general/050617 % 20- % 2oBankActsubFlNALbookmarked% 20- % 20mckj.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 693 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

conversion does not trigger statutory provisions dealing with lost" or intentionally<br />

cancelled instruments." There is however no provision dealing with a "fallback" to<br />

physical presentment upon the failure of an electronic presentment or otherwise.<br />

An innovative aspect of the Canadian approach is the amendment of the standard<br />

definition of a check 6 to include<br />

digital data and a display, printout, or other output of that data, provided<br />

the digital data, display, printout or other output was created by or from<br />

digital imaging of such bill by or on behalf of a bank by a computer system<br />

conforming to bylaws, rules or standards of the Canadian Payments<br />

Association or from the application of another technology or process<br />

conforming to bylaws, rules or standards of the Canadian Payments<br />

Association. 47<br />

It is submitted that the expansion of the definition of "cheque" is an<br />

unsatisfactory aspect of the Canadian proposal. Certainly it is not necessary to<br />

attach to the data or its output all the attributes of a "cheque." And, while the<br />

proposed definition is limited to data or output created "by or on behalf of a bank,"<br />

it is not limited to its transmission within the interbank check clearing system. A real<br />

statutory vacuum will thus be created for the transmission of the data or its output<br />

outside the interbank check clearing system. 48 Furthermore, within the interbank<br />

check clearing system, there is nothing to preclude the use of such data or its output<br />

not for presentment, but rather for negotiation, for which there is no provision in the<br />

proposal. The treatment of electronic negotiation in the United <strong>State</strong>s, discussed<br />

immediately below, is an indication to the further detail and complexity required for<br />

a fair statutory treatment of electronic negotiation.<br />

E. Electronic Negotiation<br />

The most elaborate statutory and regulatory scheme is that in the United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

covering the electronic negotiation to a collecting bank. The scheme is governed by<br />

the Check Clearing for the 21t Century Act (Check 21 Act) 49 and implemented by<br />

Regulation CC subpart D. 5 ° In essence, the Check 21 Act authorizes a collecting<br />

bank to create a substitute check, being a paper reproduction of the original check,<br />

for further negotiation or presentment. Upon compliance with specified<br />

requirements, the substitute check is to become "the legal equivalent of the original<br />

Electronic presentment must be made under the proposal "in accordance with the by-laws, rules and<br />

standards of the Canadian Payments Association." Id.<br />

43. See id.<br />

44. Bills of Exchange Act, R.S.C., ch. B-4, §§ 155-56.<br />

45. Id. § 142.<br />

46. Check is presently defined in the Bills of Exchange Act as "a bill [of exchange] drawn on a bank,<br />

payable on demand." Id. § 165(1).<br />

47. See CPA, Submission to the Department of Finance, supra note 42 (internal quotation marks<br />

omitted).<br />

48. Nor can this vacuum be filled by CPA pronouncements. For the jurisdiction of the CPA, see<br />

supra note 19.<br />

49. Check 21 Act, 12 U.S.C. §§ 5001-5018 (2004).<br />

50. 12 C.F.R. § 229 (2006).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 694 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 695<br />

check for all purposes. '' The Check 21 Act further includes warranty and<br />

indemnity provisions, as well as expedited re-credit procedures, designed to protect<br />

substitute check recipient."<br />

In practice, the creation of a substitute check by a collecting bank is predicated<br />

upon the existence of two preconditions. First, the creating bank must have received<br />

the transmission of an image of the original check instead of the check itself.<br />

Second, to receive the substitute check the bank must have not agreed to accept<br />

electronic transmission of an image.<br />

The sender of the transmission of the original check image could be either a<br />

customer, the payee-holder of the check, or a collecting bank. Either way, the<br />

creating bank is a collecting bank; it is the depositary bank where the sender is the<br />

customer, and an intermediary bank where the sender is a prior collecting bank. On<br />

its part, the bank to receive the substitute check is typically a small bank that does<br />

not have the required processing equipment. It could be either a subsequent<br />

intermediary bank or the drawee bank. 3<br />

<strong>State</strong>d differently, the Check 21 Act does not require banks to accept electronic<br />

transmission of check information or image. Rather, it requires a collecting bank<br />

that agreed to accept the electronic transmission, whether from its customer or a<br />

prior collecting bank, to issue a substitute check, to be processed onward as if it were<br />

the original check. A bank, either a subsequent collecting/intermediary bank or the<br />

drawee bank, must accept the substitute check as the equivalent of the original<br />

check. By the same token, a customer who received original checks with the<br />

periodic statement cannot object to receiving substitute checks in lieu of original<br />

checks that have been so truncated in the collection process."<br />

In practice, by truncating the paper check, the Check 21 Act eliminates longdistance<br />

transport of physical checks, though effectively it does not eliminate or<br />

bypass intra-city or local transportation for paper. The following hypothetical<br />

example will demonstrate the circumstances governed by the Check 21 Act.<br />

Suppose Drawer has a bank account with a Payor (drawee) Bank in New York.<br />

Drawer sends a check drawn on that account to Payee in California who deposits the<br />

check in Payee's account with a California Depositary Bank. The latter is a large<br />

institution that has equipment for the transmission of the image of the check. At the<br />

same time, Payor (drawee) Bank is a small institution that does not have processing<br />

equipment capable of receiving the electronic transmission of a check. There is<br />

51. Check 21 Act § 4(b), 12 U.S.C. § 5003(b); see also 12 C.F.R. § 229.51(a).<br />

52. For a comprehensive overview, though written prior to the promulgation of the final text for<br />

Regulation CC Part D, see PAUL S. TURNER, ANALYSIS OF THE CHECK CLEARING FOR THE 21' r<br />

CENTURY ACT ("CHECK 21") (2004). For more on the background to the Check 21 Act, see Availability<br />

of Funds and Collection of Checks, 69 Fed. Reg. 1470 (Jan. 8, 2004) (codified at 12 C.F.R. pt. 229) and 69<br />

Fed. Reg. 47,290 (Aug. 4, 2004) (codified at 12 C.F.R. pt. 229). See also Press Release, Federal Reserve<br />

Board, Final Amendments to Regulation CC and its Commentary to Implement Check 21 Act (July 26,<br />

2004), available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/press/bcreg/2004/20040726/default.htm; Press<br />

Release, Federal Reserve Board, Board Announces Final Amendments to Regulation J (October 22, 2004),<br />

available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/press/bcreg/2004/20041022/default.htm.<br />

53. For the various roles of banks in the check collection and payment system, see supra note 7 and<br />

accompanying text.<br />

54. An agreement of the recipient is dispensed with for a substitute check deposited, presented, sent<br />

for collection, or returned, "so long as a bank has made the warranties in [section 5] with respect to such<br />

substitute check." See Check 21 Act § 4(a), 12 U.S.C. § 5003(a).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 695 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

nothing in the UCC, the Check 21 Act, or anywhere else, to force Payor (drawee)<br />

Bank to accept electronic transmission; hence, electronic presentment is not an<br />

option for Depositary Bank. Rather, Depositary Bank may transmit the image of<br />

the check to an Intermediary Bank in New York, which is capable of accepting such<br />

transmission. 5 In effect, this is an electronic negotiation of the check. Having agreed<br />

to accept the electronic transmission, the New York Intermediary Bank is now<br />

required under the Check 21 Act to create a paper substitute check. The Act further<br />

requires Payor (drawee) Bank to accept the presentment of the substitute check as if<br />

it were the original check. Finally, any requirement, either by statute or agreement,<br />

to provide the canceled check, as under the contract between Drawer and Payor<br />

(drawee) Bank, is to be satisfied, under the Check 21 Act, by providing the<br />

substitute check.<br />

In that hypothetical example, coast-to-coast physical transportation was<br />

eliminated; only local delivery of the substitute check in New York was not avoided.<br />

A substitute check is a paper production of the original check that contains the<br />

image of the front and back of the original check, bears a MICR line containing<br />

information appearing on the MICR line of the original check, conforms,<br />

particularly in paper stock and dimension, with generally applicable for substitute<br />

checks, and is suitable for automated processing in the same manner as the original<br />

check. 56 To be the legal equivalent of the original check, a substitute check must<br />

"accurately represent ... all of the information on the front and back of the original<br />

check as of the time the original check was truncated" and bear the legend: "This is a<br />

legal copy of your check. You can use it the same way you would use the original<br />

check." 57<br />

As in the example above, a substitute check is typically created by a collecting<br />

intermediary bank. It, however, can also be created by the depositary bank, where it<br />

agreed to receive the deposit of the check from the payee by means of electronic<br />

transmission. Furthermore, a substitute check may be created even by the<br />

payee/holder; such would be the case for a large organization that receives checks in<br />

various locations but would rather deposit them in one place. The organization may<br />

then arrange for the electronic transmission of check images to one place where<br />

substitute checks will be created for deposit. In general, a check could be<br />

transformed from electronic form to substitute checks form several times in the<br />

course of the collection and return process.<br />

In connection with a substitute check, the Check 21 Act provides for warranties<br />

and an indemnity. The warranties are, first, that the substitute check meets the<br />

requirements for legal equivalence, and second, against double payment on the<br />

original check or any other representation of it." The indemnity is "to the extent of<br />

any loss incurred . . . due to the receipt of a substitute check instead of the original<br />

check." Other than for costs, expenses, and reasonable attorney's fees, the amount<br />

to be indemnified is to the extent of loss proximately caused by the breach of<br />

55. Interbank settlement between California Depositary Bank and New York Intermediary Bank may<br />

take various forms. For example, it may be either bilateral (on a correspondent account one bank has with<br />

the other), or part of multilateral clearing house settlement. If the check is collected through the Reserve<br />

Banks, settlement will take place on the books of the Reserve Banks. Check 21 Act does not deal with<br />

interbank settlement arrangements. See Check 21 Act, 12 U.S.C. §§ 5001-5018 (2004).<br />

56. Check 21 Act § 3(16), 12 U.S.C. § 5002(16); 12 C.F.R. § 229.2(aaa) (2006).<br />

57. Check 21 Act § 4(b)(2), 12 U.S.C. § 5003(b)(2); 12 C.F.R. § 229.51(a).<br />

58. Check 21 Act § 5,12 U.S.C. § 5004; 12 C.F.R. § 229.52(a).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 696 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 697<br />

warranty. In the absence of a breach of a warranty amount of indemnity is limited<br />

though to the amount of the substitute check. Either way, amount of loss to be<br />

indemnified is reduced by amount representing loss resulting "from the negligence<br />

or failure to act in good faith on the part of an indemnified party." 6 An example of<br />

loss incurred notwithstanding the lack of any breach of warranty is the case where<br />

forgery, proof of which would have allowed a purported drawer to avoid liability,<br />

cannot be proved on the substitute check, but allegedly could have been proved on<br />

the original.<br />

Substitute check warranties are given by each bank "that transfers, presents, or<br />

returns a substitute check and receives consideration for the check." 6 In turn,<br />

indemnity liability is incurred by "[a] reconverting bank and each bank that<br />

subsequently transfers, presents, or returns a substitute check in any electronic or<br />

paper form, and receives consideration for such transfer, presentment, or return...<br />

.96" A "reconverting bank" is defined as "the bank that creates a substitute check" or<br />

where "a substitute check is created by [the depositor], the first bank that transfers<br />

or presents [the] substitute check," namely, the depositary bank. 62 Surprisingly, the<br />

reconverting bank is not listed as one of the warrantors; it can hardly be described as<br />

a "bank that transfers ... a substitute check," unless "transfer" is to include the first<br />

delivery or issue; this indeed appears to be the view of the Federal Reserve. 63 In any<br />

event, the reconverting bank is listed as one to become liable to indemnify for loss<br />

caused by the breach of warranty.<br />

As indicated, a substitute check need not necessarily be created by a bank;<br />

rather it may be by a person other than a bank, typically a large organization-payee.<br />

In such a case warranties and indemnity liability emanate under the Check 21 Act<br />

not from the payee, the creator in fact of the substitute check, but rather from the<br />

first bank that transfers or presents such substitute check; such a bank, being the<br />

depositary bank, is then considered to be the "reconverting bank" in the collection<br />

process.<br />

Both substitute check warranties and the indemnity are stated to run to the<br />

benefit of the transferee, any subsequent collecting or returning bank, the depositary<br />

bank, the drawee, the drawer, the payee, the depositor, and any endorser. 6' Since a<br />

check could be transformed from electronic form to substitute checks form several<br />

times in the course of the collection and return process, it is possible that there could<br />

be multiple substitute checks, and thus multiple reconverting banks, with respect to<br />

the same payment transaction. A subsequent participant may thus benefit from<br />

warranties and indemnity of more than one reconverting bank. As well, a collecting<br />

59. Check 21 Act § 6(c), 12 U.S.C. § 5005(c); see also 12 C.F.R. § 229.53.<br />

60. Check 21 Act § 5, 12 U.S.C. § 5004.<br />

61. Check 21 Act §§ 5-6, 12 U.S.C. §§ 5004-5005 ; see also 12 C.F.R. §§ 229.52-.53.<br />

62. Check 21 Act § 3(15), 12 U.S.C. § 5002(15); see also 12 C.F.R. § 229.2 (zz).<br />

63. Check 21 Act § 3(15), 12 U.S.C. § 5002(15); see also 12 C.F.R. § 229.2 (zz). Regulation CC<br />

Commentary to section 229.52(a) states "the reconverting bank starts the flow of warranties when it<br />

transfers, presents, or returns a substitute check .... 12 C.F.R. 229 App. E XXXI (2006). The reference<br />

in the Check 21 Act to [a] bank that transfers" (section 5), as opposed to "each bank that subsequently<br />

transfers," (section 6) (which does not purport to cover the reconverting bank which is separately referred<br />

to in section 6) re-enforces this interpretation; yet, generally speaking, for a check, "issue" and "transfer"<br />

are two distinct concepts and the Act would have been clearer had it distinguished between the original<br />

issue of a substitute check and its subsequent transfer. Check 21 Act § 5-6, 12 U.S.C. § 5004-5005.<br />

64. Check 21 Act § 5-6,12 U.S.C. § 5004-5005.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 697 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

bank receiving an electronic representation of a substitute (rather than original)<br />

check will both receive and pass on the reconverting bank's Check 21 Act warranty<br />

and indemnity protections.<br />

The Check 21 Act further contains provisions covering expedited re-credit for<br />

consumers 65 and banks. First, Section 7 permits a consumer to challenge a debit for a<br />

substitute check either where the check was not properly charged to the consumer's<br />

account or where the consumer has a warranty claim. In each case the consumer<br />

must have suffered a resulting loss and the production of the original check or a<br />

better copy of it is necessary to determine the validity of the challenge or claim.<br />

Second, Section 8, governs a claim by a bank that is obligated to provide an<br />

expedited re-credit to the consumer or that has otherwise suffered loss, in<br />

circumstances where "production of the original check ... or a better copy of [it] is<br />

necessary to determine the validity of the charge to the customer account or any<br />

warranty claim connected with such substitute check." 6 The claim is a claim for<br />

indemnity from another bank that incurred the indemnity liability to the claimant<br />

bank under Section 8.67<br />

The Check 21 Act allocates losses only among banks that handle a substitute<br />

check. However, it is possible that the problem giving rise to liability under the<br />

Check 21 Act was created prior to the creation of a substitute check; for example,<br />

electronic information derived from the check may have consisted of a poor image of<br />

the original check, which would preclude the reconverting bank from creating a<br />

legally equivalent check, and thus caused it to be in breach of a substitute check<br />

warranty. Or else, a substitute check created by the payee and deposited at the<br />

depositary bank may have been deficient in one way or another. At the same time,<br />

neither warranties nor indemnity liabilities are provided in the Check 21 Act in<br />

connection with the electronic transmission of check image or information.<br />

Similarly, no warranties or indemnity liability are fastened on a payee that creates a<br />

substitute check. Responsibilities of transmitters of electronic information and<br />

depositors of substitute checks are thus to be provided by their respective contracts<br />

with the immediate recipients of electronic information and substitute checks. This<br />

indeed is quite consistent with the overall position under the Check 21 Act, under<br />

which no bank is to be required to receive electronic transmission of check data and<br />

no depositary bank is under an obligation to accept for deposit substitute checks.<br />

Having nevertheless agreed to accept such information or substitute checks, it is up<br />

for the collecting banks to do so under contractual arrangements that provide them<br />

with adequate protections.<br />

However, contract is not the exclusive source of regulating responsibilities<br />

outside the Check 21 Act; under Regulation J, a sender of an electronic item derived<br />

directly from the original check makes two sets of warranties for the electronic item.<br />

First, the sender makes transfer warranties as if the item was a paper check governed<br />

by the UCC. Second, the sender makes warranties as if the item were a substitute<br />

check governed by the Check 21 Act. 6 ' For checks handled by Reserve Banks<br />

65. "Consumer" is defined by reference to the meaning of "consumer account" in the Expedited<br />

Funds Availability Act. Check 21 Act § 3(8), 12 U.S.C. § 5002(8). A "consumer account" being "any<br />

account used primarily for personal, family, or household purposes." Expedited Funds Availability Act §<br />

602(10), 12 U.S.C. § 4001(10).<br />

66. Check 21 Act §§ 8, 12 U.S.C. §§ 5007.<br />

67. See 12 C.F.R. §§ 229.54-.55 (2006) (implementing Check 21 Act §§ 7-8, 12 U.S.C. §§ 5006-07).<br />

68. 12 C.F.R. § 210; See id. §§ 210.2-210.6, 210.12.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 698 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 699<br />

governed by Regulation J an end-to-end combined UCC and Check 21 liability<br />

structure is thus provided. 69<br />

In the final analysis, however, by reconverting an electronic image to a new<br />

piece of paper, Check 21 Act is a step backward in the process of the<br />

"immobilization" of the check. ° Rather, the Act implements the "materialization"<br />

or "certification" of the electronic image. The Act reflects a legislative policy of not<br />

forcing banks either to have their check processing facilities automated, or to<br />

outsource or contract out the function of automated processing, whether to a large<br />

bank, or a third-party processor. The result is a move away from an EFT payment,<br />

at the additional cost of a complex piece of legislation with no counterpart anywhere<br />

else in the world.<br />

III. PAYMENT CARDS - THE PAYROLL CARD AS AN ACCESS DEVICE<br />

Payment cards have been classified as either access devices or stored-value<br />

products (SVPs). 7 ' Briefly stated, a payment by means of an access device is<br />

reflected in a debit to an account maintained with a financial institution. At the<br />

same time, a payment by means of an SVP is reflected in the reduction of value<br />

stored on the card, as recorded on the card itself. Value stored on an electronic<br />

device embodied in a stored-value card is often referred to as e-money.<br />

In both access and stored-value systems, payment is initiated by having the card<br />

inserted to a terminal, 72 usually with the payment details, 73 with or without a secret<br />

code such as a PIN, entered into the terminal. Information is then read at the<br />

terminal from either a magnetic stripe or a microchips processor embodied in the<br />

card. The former reflects a cheaper technology and is typically associated with either<br />

an access card, or a low-amount stored-value card. Conversely, the latter, turning<br />

"memory card" into a "smart-card," is typically associated with the more<br />

sophisticated form of a stored-value card. The use of 'smart card' technology 'only'<br />

to enhance security features of an access card, without converting it to a store-value<br />

card, is possible, but not in use in Canada and the United <strong>State</strong>s. 74<br />

69. See generally Collection of Checks and Other Items by Federal Reserve Banks and Funds<br />

Transfers Through Fedwire, 69 Fed. Reg. 62,553 (Oct. 27, 2004) (codified at 12 C.F.R. pt. 210); Federal<br />

Reserve Bank of New York, Final Amendment to Regulation J: Collection of Checks and Other Items,<br />

Circular No. 11653 (October 25, 2004).<br />

70. For the borrowed use of "decertification," "dematerialization," and "immobilization" in this<br />

context, see supra note 11 and accompanying text.<br />

71. For the basic distinction between access devices and stored-value products, see, e.g. COMM. ON<br />

PAYMENT & SETTLEMENT SYS., SECURITY OF ELECTRONIC MONEY 3 (1996). See generally, Benjamin<br />

Geva & Muharem Kianieff, Reimagining E-Money: Its Conceptual Unity with Other Retail Payment<br />

Systems, in 3 CURRENT DEVELOPMENTS IN MONETARY AND FINANCIAL LAW 669 (2005).<br />

72. A public access terminal can be either at a point of sale (POS) for the payment of goods or<br />

services purchased, or at an automated teller machine (ATM) for strictly cash withdrawals, with or without<br />

other banking operations. Where on the top of cash withdrawals additional banking operations are<br />

facilitated, the terminal may be referred to as an automated banking machine (ABM).<br />

73. It is, however, possible, though not common, to have the terminal programmed to charge payment<br />

in a specified amount. This is the case for telephone and transit cards, and often for cards inserted to<br />

unattended terminals at parking lots.<br />

74. See Benjamin Geva, Consumer Liability in Unauthorized Electronic Funds Transfers, 38 CAN.<br />

BUS. L. J. 207, 212-23 (2003) [hereinafter Geva, Consumer Liability] (detailing various methods of<br />

authorization and the evolution of retail card payment systems).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 699 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

Where the card is an access device, information read from the card at the<br />

terminal is then transmitted from the terminal to a central facility of the financial<br />

institution where the account associated with the card is maintained; both card<br />

authentication and the debit to the account take place at such a central facility.<br />

Conversely, where the card is stored-value, no information is transmitted from the<br />

terminal to any central facility; both authentication and the posting of the debit<br />

occur at the terminal.<br />

In the United <strong>State</strong>s, access devices are either credit cards, governed by the<br />

Consumer Credit Protection Act 7 5 and implemented by Regulation Z, 76 or debit<br />

cards, governed by the Electronic Fund Transfer Act 77 and implemented by<br />

Regulation E." 8 While payment by credit card is to be debited to a credit account<br />

maintained with a financial institution, 79 payment by debit card is to be debited to an<br />

asset, such a deposit, account, maintained with a financial institution.<br />

8 0 Payment<br />

recorded on an SVP is not debited to an account maintained at the financial<br />

institution; the SVP thus falls outside the ambit of an existing specific legislation.<br />

In practice, multi-participant stored-value ("open") systems have not made a<br />

breakthrough in North America where the typical stored-value card is still associated<br />

with a "closed" system such as telephone or transit. 8 ' On its part, the typical debit or<br />

credit card envisages access by the cardholder to his or her account maintained by<br />

the financial institution. In recent years, however, various systems have arisen in the<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s under which a deposit account is specifically set up for an exclusive<br />

access by a card;2 in turn, the asset account may be held or set up at a financial<br />

institution by a person other than the cardholder. Such is the case with respect to a<br />

payroll, remittance, or gift cards, as well as reloadable general spending cards. Thus,<br />

a card provider or marketer establishes a "pooled" or master account with its<br />

financial institution. The financial institution issues cards and assumes fiduciary or<br />

trust obligations for the benefit of the cardholders, as designated or recruited by the<br />

card provider or marketer. A third-party service provider may be charged with<br />

transaction processing, program administration, and customer services. For<br />

example, a payroll cardholder is an employee whose wages are deposited by the<br />

employer, acting as the card provider, to a "pooled" or master account from which<br />

the employee can make payments up to the value associated with the card, as capped<br />

by his or her wages. A remittance or gift card gives access to value deposited in a<br />

master account held by a money transmitter. In each case, the account relationship<br />

75. 15 U.S.C. § 1631 (approved in 1968).<br />

76. Truth in Lending, 12 C.F.R. § 226 (2006).<br />

77. 15 U.S.C. § 1693 (implemented in 1978).<br />

78. 12 C.F.R. § 205.<br />

79. Note that the issuer of a credit card need not necessarily be financial institution. See 12 C.F.R. §§<br />

226.2(a)(14)-(15) (defining "credit" and "credit card").<br />

80. See 12 C.F.R. §§ 205.2(b)(1), 205.3 (defining "account" and "coverage").<br />

81. For the distinction, as well as for development in the United <strong>State</strong>s and a legal perspective, see<br />

Task Force on Stored-Value Cards, A Commercial <strong>Law</strong>yer's Take on the Electronic Purse: An Analysis of<br />

Commercial <strong>Law</strong> Issues Associated with Stored-Value Cards and Electronic Money, 52 Bus. LAW. 653<br />

(1997). In contrast, a multi-participant stored-value ("open") system has been successful for small-value<br />

transactions, for example, in Hong Kong. For a Canadian perspective, see Shameela Chinoy, Electronic<br />

Money in Electronic Purses and Wallets, 12 BANKING & FIN. L. REV. 15 (1996); Bradly Crawford, Is<br />

Electronic Money Really Money?, 12 BANKING & FIN. L. REV. 399 (1996).<br />

82. As of 1996, "[s]o far as [the FDIC was] aware, the systems of this type [were] not currently being<br />

utilized by depository institutions." Notice of FDIC General Counsel's Opinion No. 8, 61 Fed. Reg. 40,490<br />

n.1 (Aug. 2, 1996).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 700 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 701<br />

with the financial institution in which the master account is held envisages access<br />

only by means of the card, but the relationship is between the financial institution<br />

and the holder of the master account, the card provider or marketer, who is a person<br />

other than the cardholder; yet, it is each cardholder who is entitled, at least vis-A-vis<br />

the person who set up the master account, and as facilitated by the financial<br />

institution in which the master account is maintained, to the value attached to the<br />

card. Indeed, a direct relationship may be established between the financial<br />

institution and the cardholder as to the use of the card; at the same time, the overall<br />

account relationship is between the financial institution and the card provider or<br />

marketer who set it up, such as the money transmitter or employer. <strong>State</strong>d<br />

otherwise, the cardholder is a sub-account holder; his or her sub-account relationship<br />

is, however, with the account holder, the card provider or marketer who is the<br />

employer or money transmitter in the previous examples, and not directly with the<br />

financial institution. 83<br />

It is submitted that, fundamentally, such an arrangements is an access system;<br />

indeed, a recent amendment to Regulation E expands the scope of Regulation E to<br />

cover payroll cards, 8' subject only to some incidental modifications, reflecting the<br />

lack of direct account relationship between the cardholder and the financial<br />

institution." Unfortunately, however, both in the literature and banking parlance,<br />

cards accessing non-cardholder master accounts, are referred to as prepaid or storedvalue<br />

cards.' It is submitted that this is conceptually wrong, which may lead to<br />

confusion and misunderstandings.<br />

It seems that the source of this misconception is a classification of the Federal<br />

Reserve Board under which stored-value systems may be offline accountable, offline<br />

unaccountable, and online stored value; 87 arguably, the third category, that of online<br />

stored value, could be referred to as online accountable. According to the Board, in<br />

an offline accountable system, payment does not involve an online authorization;<br />

transaction data is however periodically transmitted to the financial institution and<br />

recorded in an account maintained there for the cardholder. An offline<br />

83. See, e.g., Sherrie L.W. Rhine & Sabrina Su, Stored Value Cards as a Method of Electronic Payment<br />

for Unbanked Consumers, 9-11 (2005), available at<br />

http://www.newyorkfed.org/regional/StoredValue-Card-Paper-August-2005.pdf; see also Julia S.<br />

Cheney, Payment Cards and the Unbanked: Prospects and Challenges 11-12 (2005), available at<br />

http://www.philadelphiafed.org/pcc/conferences/2005/PaymentCardsandtheUnbankedSummary.pdf; James<br />

C. McGrath, The Cost Effectiveness of Stored-Value Products for Unbanked Consumers 4-11 (2005),<br />

available at http://www.philadelphiafed.org/pcc/papers/2005/D2005MarchUnbankedCover.pdf; Samuel<br />

Frumkin, William Reeves & Barry Wides, Payroll Cards: An Innovative Product for Reaching the<br />

Unbanked and Underbanked 1-6 (June 2005), http://www.occ.treas.gov/cdd/payrollcards.pdf.<br />

84. See 12 C.F.R. § 205.2(b)(2) (effective July 1, 2007) (defining "Account" to include "payroll card<br />

account" which is "an account that is directly or indirectly established through an employer and to which<br />

electronic fund transfers of the consumer's wages, salary, or other employee compensation ... are made on<br />

a recurring basis ... whether the account is operated or managed by the employer, a third-party payroll<br />

processor, [or] a depositary institution .... "); see also Final Rule, 71 Fed. Reg. 51,437, 51437-51,439 (Aug.<br />

30, 2006) (codified at 12 C.F.R. pt. 205).<br />

85. See 12 C.F.R. § 205.18 (effective July 1, 2007) (stating that financial institutions need not provide<br />

periodic statements under 12 C.F.R. § 205.9, if they make required information available to the consumer<br />

via telephone, the Internet, or in writing upon request).<br />

86. See Geva, Consumer Liability, supra note 74.<br />

87. See Electronic Funds Transfers, 61 Fed. Reg. 19,696, 19,699-19,703 (May 2, 1996) (codified at 12<br />

C.F.R. pt. 205).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 701 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

unaccountable system does not involve online authorization; record of value is<br />

maintained only on the card itself. Finally, an online stored value (or accountable)<br />

system involves both online authorization and transmission of data to a centralized<br />

account with no record of value being maintained on the card.<br />

In my view, the Board's classification ought to apply to both access and storevalue<br />

systems. Along these lines I disagree with the classification of the offline<br />

accountable and online accountable systems as stored-value. According to my<br />

revised classification, card payment systems may well be classified as offline<br />

unaccountable, offline accountable, or online accountable. The online/offline<br />

distinction addresses the existence or absence of communication between the<br />

terminal and a central facility with regard to authorization. In the former case the<br />

system is "online"; in the latter it is "offline." The accountable/unaccountable<br />

distinction addresses the debiting of either an account held by an institution<br />

(typically the issuer) or a "decentralized" account maintained on the card in the<br />

form of a decrease of the value "loaded" on it. In the former case the system is<br />

"accountable"; in the latter it is "unaccountable." Whether a product is an access or<br />

stored-value depends on whether it is accountable or unaccountable; it is an access<br />

product in the former and an SVP in the latter case.<br />

Practically speaking, an online system is bound to be accountable. This is so<br />

even though the central facility for the online authorization may not be same as the<br />

central facility posting entries to the account; once communication to the central<br />

facility occurs, there is simply no incentive for bypassing "centralized"<br />

accountability. At the same time, bypassing altogether online authorization is only<br />

likely, but not bound, to lead to non-accountability; technological limitations<br />

inherent in the card, such as those associated with the magnetic stripe technology,<br />

may preclude or limit the bypassing of accountability. In this context, one source of<br />

confusion is what could be characterized as a "quasi accountable" system, in which<br />

value is both reduced from the card, at the time payment is made, but also from an<br />

account at a central facility, to which the information is subsequently transmitted<br />

periodically.<br />

The proposed revised classification, covering access and stored-value cards,<br />

takes into account the above in making the following options available:<br />

1) An "online accountable" system. This is the typical credit and debit card<br />

system, utilizing magnetic stripe cards; it is an access system in which each payment<br />

made from a terminal typically involves communication between the terminal and a<br />

central facility and results in a debit to an account held by a financial institution. In<br />

my view, also the payroll card (as well as the remittance and gift card) falls into this<br />

category; it is immaterial that the account maintained by the central facility at the<br />

financial institution and to be debited is a master account set up by the employer<br />

rather than the cardholder. The card is thus an access device; while I agree with the<br />

Board that the value attached to this card is limited to a specified amount and is to<br />

be accessed only by the card, I do not see this as a feature which changes the basic<br />

nature of the account containing the value as an asset account; limitations on the<br />

withdrawals facilities of an account have nothing to do with its fundamental nature.<br />

In effect, the Board's view to the contrary is fraught with inconsistencies; having<br />

classified the system as stored-value, the Board nevertheless concluded that the<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 702 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 703<br />

account to be debited on an online stored-value system is an asset account "covered<br />

by Regulation E." '<br />

2) An "offline unaccountable" system. This is e-money loaded on an SVP pure<br />

and simple. Typically, the card is a "smart card." Authorization occurs at the<br />

terminal and value is reduced only from the card. There may be later<br />

"accountability" in the sense of ability to match value paid (by cardholder-payor)<br />

and value deposited (by payee) and attributed to a given card-but this is not part of<br />

the payment process; rather, this is a method to track down payments as may be<br />

required. Hence, this "accountability" is to be disregarded for our purposes.'<br />

3) An "offline-accountable" system. In my view, an example to the point may<br />

be that of the credit card authorized only at the terminal with subsequent off-line<br />

communication to the central facility that debits the cardholder's (credit) account.<br />

The card is however an access device as no value is deducted in the process of the atthe-terminal<br />

authorization. Typically, the card utilizes the magnetic-stripe<br />

technology, which has only limited capacity to be "loaded" with value. As explained<br />

below, what is described by the Board as "offline accountable" is fact "offline quasiaccountable";<br />

to the extent that value recorded on the card is available on its own<br />

the periodic transmission to the financial institution is only for verification.<br />

4) An "offline quasi accountable" system. This is likely to be the case for<br />

telephone and transit cards; value is reduced at the terminal (as part of the offline<br />

authorization process); the process is however followed by an off-line<br />

communication in batches to a central facility that debits a "centralized" "shadow"<br />

account attached to the card. Typically, cards that fall into this category are not<br />

smart cards but rather those bearing "magnetic stripe." This is so since the<br />

information they carry is limited: there is no PIN and value is rather low. But it is<br />

this "inferior" technology that results in enhanced opportunities for counterfeiters<br />

and hence the need for an ongoing verification of authenticity in the form of the<br />

offline communication to a central facility. In the final analysis, however, so far as<br />

the cardholder is concerned, available value was reduced at the terminal and the<br />

subsequent debit of the shadow account is to confirm authenticity; the system is thus<br />

to be classified as a sub-category of an "unaccountable" rather than "accountable"<br />

system. <strong>State</strong>d otherwise, a "quasi accountable" system is not truly "accountable"<br />

and the system is an SVP.<br />

5) Either an "online unaccountable" or "online quasi accountable" system<br />

exists only in theory; once online communication takes place, there is no point to<br />

bypass the posting of entries to the account held at the financial institution; stated<br />

otherwise, there is no business case for "unaccountability."<br />

On its part, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) proposes to<br />

"promulgate a regulation that would clarify the insurance coverage of funds subject<br />

to transfer or withdrawal through the use of stored value cards and other<br />

nontraditional access mechanisms." '9 Covering "nontraditional access mechanisms,"<br />

88. Id. at 19,699.<br />

89. See Alan L. Tyree, The Legal Nature of Electronic Money, 10 Journal Banking & Fin. L. & Prac.<br />

273, 276 (1999) (describing "accounts" maintained on devices which are under the control of the customer,<br />

such as cards, as "decentralized" or "distributed" so as to distinguish it from the centralized account run in<br />

a central facility in an access system).<br />

90. See Deposit Insurance Coverage; Stored Value Cards and Other Nontraditional Access<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 703 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

the proposed Regulation describes a card falling into this category as a mechanism<br />

providing "access to funds received and held by an insured depository institution for<br />

payment to others."'" Purporting to cover in section 330.5 (c)(2) of the proposed<br />

Regulation e-money purchased from and held at the issuer depository institution,<br />

the FDIC proposed that "funds placed at an insured depository institution by one<br />

party for transfer or withdrawal by same party... shall be deposits belonging to the<br />

same party." ' This appears to cover funds paid for the purchase of e-money loaded<br />

on a stored-value card, which remain at the institution available for redemption.<br />

With respect to "funds placed at an insured depository institution by one party<br />

for withdrawal by other parties," the FDIC proposes in section 330.5(c)(3) that<br />

unless two conditions are to be satisfied, funds will be insurable to the party that<br />

places the funds and not the actual cardholders. These conditions are first, "the<br />

account records of the insured depository institution reflect the fact that the first<br />

party is not the owner of the funds," and second, either the party that places the<br />

funds or the depository institution "maintains records reflecting the identities of the<br />

persons holding the [cards] and the amount payable to each person., 93 Only when<br />

these conditions are fulfilled, insurance will benefit the cardholders. 94 Accordingly,<br />

insurance will benefit holders of payroll cards but not anonymous purchasers of gift<br />

cards; under the same logic, insurance will also not cover anonymous cardholders of<br />

remittance cards, and in fact merchants and other payees paid by cards governed by<br />

the proposed new regulation. 9<br />

In effectively dealing separately with "true" stored value cards (under<br />

paragraph (c)(2)) and cards accessing funds placed by marketer or card provider<br />

(under paragraph (c)(3)), the FDIC did not fail to see that the two situations are<br />

distinct. Yet, it purports to promulgate one rule applicable to both situations.<br />

Furthermore, the language of paragraph (c)(2), covering "funds placed at an insured<br />

depository institution by one party for transfer or withdrawal by same party,"<br />

appears to apply to not only to funds paid for the purchase of e-money loaded on a<br />

stored-value card, which remain at the institution available for redemption, but also<br />

to funds accessed by a debit card accessing the cardholder's account. Thus, the<br />

FDIC did not go far enough to highlight the nature of the stored-value card as<br />

distinct from the "traditional" access card, issued to an account holder. In the final<br />

Mechanisms, 70 Fed. Reg. 45,578, 45,578-45,580 (Aug. 8, 2005) (proposing to amend 12 C.F.R. § 330.5 by<br />

adding a new paragraph in which "access" is used by reference to specific funds deposited as opposed to<br />

the account under which they are managed).<br />

91. Id. at 45,580.<br />

92. But see Notice of FDIC General Counsel's Opinion No. 8, 61 Fed. Reg. 40,490, 40,491-40,494<br />

(Aug. 2, 1996). The Notice states that such funds are not insured for the benefit of the cardholder where<br />

they are placed in a reserve account rather than frozen in the cardholder's account. Id. The proposed rule<br />

does not seem to follow that distinction. Id.<br />

93. Id.<br />

94. Id.<br />

95. Cf. 12 U.S.C. § 1822(c) (limiting protection to depositors whose name appears on bank records).<br />

But cf 12 C.F.R. § 330.5(b)(4) (2006) (providing insurance coverage for deposits evidenced by a negotiable<br />

instrument such as "certificate of deposit, negotiable draft, negotiable cashier's or officer's check,<br />

negotiable certified check, [or] negotiable traveler's check" whose holder is not on bank records).<br />

Certainly, identifying cardholders of "low value" cards not on bank records may be a costly and laborintensive<br />

task. The question is whether exclusion from insurance coverage on such grounds is nevertheless<br />

justified for anonymous cardholders and payees with "high value" claims as well as of anyone actually<br />

coming forward by presenting a valid claim for redemption. Payee's claim to insurance may arise where<br />

payment on the card, as opposed to the redemption of its value, could not have been stopped.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 704 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 705<br />

analysis, while being cognizant of the distinction, and yet in focusing on the<br />

communality, between the two "nontraditional access mechanisms" to be governed<br />

by the proposed Regulation, the FDIC may have inadvertently blurred the<br />

distinction between access to stored-value cards.<br />

No comprehensive legislation regarding SVPs is forthcoming in the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s. The expansion of Regulation E to cover the payroll card is a laudable<br />

pragmatic step taken in the right direction; yet, in my view, it is important to<br />

recognize that action taken is not the application of debit card law to a stored-value<br />

card. Rater, it is a recognition that the payroll card is an access device. Similarly,<br />

lumping up stored-value and funds placed by a third party into one category of<br />

"nontraditional access mechanisms," as was done by the FDIC, does not enhance<br />

clarity. In the long run it is important to either repudiate or reconstruct the<br />

conceptual framework set out by the Federal Reserve Board expanding the storedvalue<br />

category to cover situations that do not belong to it.<br />

IV. SECURITIES TRANSFERS IN THE INDIRECT HOLDING SYSTEM -<br />

LAW REFORM IN CANADA IN THE FOOTSTEPS OF UCC ARTICLE 896<br />

Historically, securities 9 ' were issued solely directly, by their issuers to securities<br />

holders, in a form of bearer, order, or registrable certificate. A transfer of a<br />

registrable security was "perfected," so as to confer on the transferee ownership and<br />

legal title to the security, by registration on the issuer's books. A transfer by a<br />

holder of a registered security required the physical delivery of the certificate<br />

accompanied by an endorsement. It was completed by the following steps: (i) the<br />

surrender by the transferee of the transferor's certificate to the issuer, (ii) the<br />

cancellation of the transferor's certificate by the issuer, (iii) the replacement of the<br />

transferor's name by that of the transferee on the books of the issuer, and (iv) the<br />

issue by the issuer of a new certificate to the transferee, in the transferee's own<br />

name. Typically, the transferor would deliver the certificate and an indorsement in<br />

blank to his or her broker, who would deliver this documentation to the transferee's<br />

broker, for further action.<br />

In the original form of the direct holding system, possession and delivery of<br />

physical certificates were key elements. 98 One response to the resulting paper crisis<br />

was immobilization or uncertification. For immobilized or uncertificated securities,<br />

no certificate was to be issued to registrable securities holders, whose rights were<br />

thus to be evidenced solely by the registration on the issuer's book. In any event, the<br />

new system did not supersede altogether, and in practice, hardly challenged, the<br />

96. See generally Benjamin Geva, Promoting Stability in International Finance-Legislative and<br />

Regulatory Reform of Payment and Settlement Systems, in 18 THE REFORM OF THE INTERNATIONAL<br />

FINANCIAL ARCHITECTURE 247-81 (Rosa M. Lastra ed., Intern'l Banking, Fin. & Econ. <strong>Law</strong> Series No. 18,<br />

2001).<br />

97. See BLACK'S LAW DICTIONARY 1358 (7th ed. 1999) (broadly speaking, "security" denotes an<br />

obligation of or an equity in an issuer which is of a type dealt in or traded on financial or exchange markets<br />

or is otherwise a medium of investment).<br />

98. See Colonial Bank v. Cady, (1890) 15 App. Cas. 267 (H.L.) (U.K.) (providing a classic common<br />

law case on the effect of possession of the endorsed certificate); see also ALBERTA LAW REFORM INST.,<br />

TRANSFERS OF INVESTMENT SECURITIES 67 (1993) (giving the historical evolution of securities from a<br />

Canadian perspective).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 705 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

traditional certificated one. Rather, in principle, both systems co-exist, and<br />

depending on the terms of the issue, new securities could be issued in either<br />

certificated or uncertificated/immobilized form. In practice, the certificated system<br />

has remained prevalent. 99<br />

In any event, the uncertificated system has been a direct holding variant. In its<br />

framework, the transfer of a registrable security still contemplates registration on the<br />

book of the issuer, albeit on the basis of an instruction sent to the issuer, without the<br />

mechanism of delivering, surrendering and cancelling a certificate and the issue of a<br />

new one. Immobilization or uncertification has thus proved to be a mere partial<br />

solution which failed altogether to address the crux of the matter, that of the<br />

emergence of the indirect (or tiered) holding system. Thereunder, securities,<br />

whether in a certificated or uncertificated form, are issued to a clearing corporation<br />

or agency such as a central depository of securities (CDS) which then allocates rights<br />

in them to financial intermediaries, such as securities brokers and banks, as<br />

purchased by the intermediaries from the issuer. In turn, each financial intermediary<br />

then sells rights to investors. In such a system, the CDS remains the registered<br />

securities holder. Neither change in the registration on the books of the issuer, nor<br />

in the context of a certificated system, the issue of a new certificate, effectuates the<br />

subsequent transactions. Rather, the rights acquired by a purchaser are reflected as<br />

a credit or book-entry in an account held by that purchaser with an upper tier<br />

financial intermediary. To pursue our example, a brokerage firm purchasing a<br />

defined quantity of securities from the issuer will have its account with the CDS<br />

credited to that extent. Similarly, an investor, client of such a brokerage firm, will<br />

have his or her account with the brokerage firm credited, to the extent of the amount<br />

purchased. Transactions among brokers are effectuated on the books of CDS.<br />

Transactions among customers are effectuated on books held by brokers or other<br />

financial intermediaries. Interests in securities are thus held indirectly, through<br />

securities intermediaries.<br />

A few important characteristics of this indirect holding system could be<br />

elaborated as follows:<br />

1) The system does not preclude the registration of any interest on the books<br />

of the issuer. <strong>State</strong>d otherwise, an interested holder can require, through the<br />

intermediary who maintains the interest holder's account, the establishment of a<br />

direct relationship with this intermediary's upper-tier institution, and ultimately,<br />

with the issuer. In fact, only a direct relationship with the issuer will secure to an<br />

investor a direct access to dividends or interest as well as the exercise of membership<br />

rights in the assembly or otherwise in management of the issuer, per the terms<br />

attached to the security. Yet, registration on the books of the issuer so as to<br />

establish such a direct relationship is a costly and timely process, in which most<br />

investors are not interested. This explains the popularity of the indirect holding<br />

system.<br />

99. Thus, in both the United <strong>State</strong>s and Canada, the uncertificated system has not made significant<br />

inroads. In the United <strong>State</strong>s, the uncertificated system, though accommodated by the 1978 revision of<br />

U.C.C. Article 8, has not developed for most categories of securities. It was thus observed that "[mlutual<br />

funds shares have long been issued in uncertificated form, but virtually all other forms of publicly traded<br />

corporate securities are still issued in certificated form." U.C.C. revised art. 8, Prefatory Note I(B) (1994).<br />

In Canada, uncertificated securities have been even less widespread. Regardless, in both the United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

and Canada, mutual funds securities are not transferable, only redeemable. Hence they do not raise any<br />

issue relating to transferability.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 706 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 707<br />

2) The pattern set out above should not mislead the reader to assume that the<br />

indirect holding system is necessarily exclusively a two-tiered one. In fact, further<br />

extensive financial intermediation may take place, particularly in the context of<br />

international finance.<br />

3) Typically, in the indirect holding system, where a certificate is issued to the<br />

CDS, the original certificate so issued by the issuer to the CDS, is a "jumbo<br />

certificate," reflecting the entire issue. In the normal course of events, that is, where<br />

no remote investor seeks to establish a direct relationship with the issuer, this<br />

certificate will remain stored with and untouched by the CDS. In this context, we<br />

speak of the "dematerialization of the security." Unlike immobilization or<br />

uncertification which exclude the issue of a certificate in the first place,<br />

dematerialization contemplates the issue of an original certificate which is put out of<br />

use.<br />

4) A holder of an interest has no entitlement to any specific security. Rather,<br />

the entitlement is to a specific quantity of a fungible asset as credited to the security<br />

holder's security account. Inter-financial intermediary transactions are thus not<br />

cleared and settled individually, but rather, in a fashion similar to the clearing and<br />

settlement of money transfers.<br />

Not surprisingly, the law governing securities transfers has been concerned with<br />

the direct holding system. This law is thus ill-fit to provide a comprehensive and<br />

clear framework for the indirect holding system. While the law relating to the direct<br />

holding system focuses on the relationship between the issuer and the security<br />

holder, the indirect holding system revolves around relationships involving<br />

intermediaries. Put another way, in the direct holding system the asset under<br />

discussion is the security itself. Conversely, in the indirect holding system, the asset<br />

under discussion is the entitlement to a security as reflected in an account<br />

maintained by a financial intermediary.<br />

To accommodate the indirect holding system in the context of laws governing<br />

securities transfers Guynn set out four fundamental principles of law reform:""<br />

[1)] Interests in securities held through a financial intermediary should be<br />

defined ... as [an] interest in a pro-rata portion of the pool of securities or<br />

interests in securities held by the intermediary with whom the interest<br />

holder has a direct contractual relationship . . . . The interest should<br />

exclusively be reflected as a credit to the interest holder's account with the<br />

intermediary, and not as a traceable property right in individual securities<br />

or a mere contractual claim.<br />

[2)] The pool of securities or interests in securities held by a financial<br />

intermediary to satisfy the interest of its interest holders should be<br />

protected against the claims of the intermediary's general creditors ....<br />

This can be done either by defining the interest as a type of property or coproperty<br />

right or by amending existing.., laws governing the insolvencies<br />

of "financial intermediaries to give explicit effect to this policy.<br />

100. Randall D. Guynn, Modernizing Securities Ownership, Transfer and Pledging <strong>Law</strong>s: A<br />

Discussion Paper on the Need for International Harmonization 33-37 (Capital Markets Forum. Intern'l Bar<br />

Assoc. 1996), available at http://www.dpw.com/iba.modernization.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 707 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL VOL. 42:685<br />

[3)] Conflicts of laws rules should be interpreted or modernized to reflect<br />

the development of the [indirect holding] system [to accommodate]<br />

holding, transferring and pledging interests in securities by [means of]<br />

book-entry to accounts with financial intermediaries so that the selection<br />

of the law governing the [rights in such a system ought to be] determined<br />

by agreement, [and] in the absence of such agreement, by reference to<br />

where the office of the financial intermediary maintaining such accounts is<br />

located or otherwise by reference to the intermediary's jurisdiction.<br />

[4)] Procedures for creating and enforcing a pledge of [or security]<br />

interests in securities credited to accounts with intermediaries should be<br />

simplified.<br />

1<br />

Guynn enumerated three enactments that appear already to satisfy these four<br />

basic principles so as to be models for reform. One such enactment is Revised<br />

Article 8 (1994 Official Text) of the Uniform Commercial Code in the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s." An important update 0 3 is the adoption by the Canadian provinces of<br />

Alberta" ° and Ontario 5 of a Uniform Securities Transfers Act (USTA), ° closely<br />

modelled on UCC Revised Article 8.<br />

101. Id. at 33-34 (asserting that this principle is consistent with an informed application of the lex situs<br />

rule). Guynn goes on to elaborate several applications as follows:<br />

[i] the substantive law governing the validity of securities and the rights and duties of issuers<br />

should be the law of the issuer's jurisdiction"; [(ii)] the law governing any contest between the<br />

rights of any person identified as the holder of an interest in dematerialized securities directly<br />

on the books of an issuer or its agent and the rights of any adverse claimant in such interest<br />

should be the law where the books are located (typically the issuer's jurisdiction)"; [(iii)] "the<br />

law governing any contest between the rights of persons that have actual possession of physical<br />

securities and those of any adverse claimant in such physical securities should be the law where<br />

the physical securities are located"; [(iv)] "the law governing the rights and duties of an<br />

intermediary with respect to interests in securities credited to accounts with it, as well as any<br />

contest between the rights of any person identified as the holder of such an interest on the<br />

books of the intermediary and those of any adverse claimant in such interest, should be the law<br />

where the intermediary's office maintaining such accounts is located or otherwise by the law of<br />

the intermediary's jurisdiction.<br />

Id. at 36.<br />

102. See id. at 43-45 (explaining that the two other enactments are (i) "the Belgian Royal Decree No.<br />

62 dated November 10, 1967 Facilitating the Circulation of Securities (as amended, April 7, 1995)"; and<br />

(ii) the Luxembourg Grand-Ducal Decrees of February 17, 1971, December 18, 1991 and June 8, 1994").<br />

103. See generally UNIDROIT Study Group, Harmonised Substantive Rules Regarding Indirectly<br />

Held Securities (2003), available at<br />

http://www.unidroit.org/english/publications/proceedings/2003/study/78/s-78-08-e.pdf (discussing such<br />

issues from a more global perspective). For subsequent developments and comments, see generally<br />

UNIDROIT Web-site, Intermediated Securities - Study LXXVIII,<br />

http://www.unidroit.org/english/workprogramme/study078/iteml/main.htm (last visited May 16, 2007).<br />

104. Securities Transfer Act, S.A. 2006, ch. S-4.5 (Alberta), available at<br />

http://www.canlii.org/ab/laws/sta/s-4.5/20070312/whole.html.<br />

105. Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8 (Ontario) [hereinafter Ontario Securities Transfer Act],<br />

available at http://www.canlii.org/on/laws/sta/2006c.8/20070307/whole.html.<br />

106. See generally CANADIAN SECURITIES ADMINISTRATORS' UNIFORM SECURITIES ACT TASK<br />

FORCE, PROPOSAL FOR A MODERNIZED UNIFORM LAW IN CANADA GOVERNING THE HOLDING.<br />

TRANSFER AND PLEDGING OF SECURITIES (May 28. 2004). available at<br />

http://www.osc.gov.on.ca/MarketRegulation/SpecialProjects/usta/usta-20040528_consultation-paper.pdf;<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 708 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 709<br />

Article 8 and USTA are not limited to indirect securities holding. Rather, they<br />

are comprehensive pieces of legislation covering also the direct holding of<br />

certificated and uncertificated securities. The ensuing discussion will outline the<br />

principal features of Article 8 and the Ontario Securities Transfer Act (OSTA) as a<br />

model for legislative reform.' 7<br />

Both Revised Article 8 and OSTA abandon any attempt to describe all of the<br />

complex relationships in the indirect holding system using the simple concepts of the<br />

traditional holding system. For example, the investors' interests are not described as<br />

co-ownership in securities held for their benefit by a broker. Instead, vis- -vis a<br />

"securities intermediary" maintaining for him or her a "securities account," the<br />

"entitlement holder," such as an investor or another "securities intermediary," has a<br />

''security entitlement" to a "financial asset" held by that "securities intermediary."<br />

In turn, the "financial asset" held by the "securities intermediary" to meet its<br />

obligations to satisfy the "security entitlements" of its customers, namely those for<br />

whom it maintains "securities accounts," is itself a "security entitlement" to a<br />

"financial asset" held by another "securities intermediary." Only ultimately, the<br />

"financial asset" held by the clearing corporation (such as a CDS) to whom the<br />

security was originally issued, is the security itself. 1 " 8<br />

The specific provisions of Part 5 of Revised UCC Article 8 and Part VI of<br />

OSTA, each bearing the title "security entitlement" and dealing with the indirect<br />

holding of securities, can be outlined as follows. In principle, the acquisition of a<br />

financial asset is to be reflected as a credit in a securities account.'0 9 An action based<br />

on an adverse claim to a financial asset may not be asserted against a person who<br />

acquires a security entitlement for value and without notice of the adverse claim." 0<br />

Financial assets held by a securities intermediary to satisfy securities entitlements<br />

"are not property of the securities intermediary, and are not subject to claims of<br />

creditors of the securities intermediary.""' Rather, entitlement holders share them<br />

pro rata."' A securities intermediary is required to maintain a financial asset in a<br />

see also Eric T. Spink & Maxime A. Par6, The Uniform Securities Transfer Act: Globalized Commercial<br />

<strong>Law</strong> for Canada, 19 BANKING & FIN. L. REV. 321 (2004); Benjamin Geva, Legislative Power in Relation to<br />

Transfers of Securities: The Case for Provincial Jurisdiction in Canada, 19 BANKING & FIN. L. REV. 393<br />

(2004).<br />

107. See generally James Steven Rogers, Policy Perspectives on Revised U.C.C. Article 8, 43 UCLA L.<br />

REV. 1431 (1996) (providing detailed discussion on article 8 by the reporter to the revised article 8 drafting<br />

committee).<br />

108. Pertinent definitions are set out in U.C.C. sections 8-102 and 8-501 as well as in OSTA section 1.<br />

Briefly stated, a "securities intermediary" is either "(i) a clearing corporation; or (ii) a person, including a<br />

bank or broker, that in the ordinary course of its business maintains securities accounts for others ...."<br />

U.C.C. § 8-102(a)(14 (2006): Ontario Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, § 1. A "securities account"<br />

is "an account to which a financial asset is or may be credited ...." U.C.C. § 8-501(a); Ontario Securities<br />

Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, § 1. A "financial asset" is either "a security [or] property that is held by a<br />

securities intermediary for another person in a securities account ...." U.C.C. § 8-102(a)(9); Ontario<br />

Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, § 1. "Security entitlement" is the rights and property interest of<br />

an entitlement holder with respect to a financial asset. U.C.C. § 8-102(a)(17). An "entitlement holder" is<br />

"a person identified in the records of a securities intermediary as the person having a security entitlement<br />

against the securities intermediary." U.C.C. § 8-102(a)(7); Ontario Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch.<br />

8,§ 1.<br />

109. U.C.C. § 8-501(b): Ontario Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, § 95.<br />

110. U.C.C. § 8-502: Ontario Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, § 96.<br />

111. U.C.C. §8-503(a).<br />

112. U.C.C. §8-503(b); Ontario Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, § 97(2); see also U.C.C. § 8-<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 709 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

quantity corresponding to the aggregate of all security entitlements it has established<br />

in favour of its entitlement holders with respect to that financial asset." 3 <strong>State</strong>d<br />

otherwise, unlike a bank account, a securities account is backed by 100% reserve. A<br />

securities intermediary is responsible to its entitlement holders to obtain and<br />

distribute any payment made by the issuer of the financial asset and is further<br />

obliged to exercise rights with respect to a financial asset as directed by the<br />

entitlement holder.1 4 A securities intermediary is further required to comply with<br />

the entitlement holder's instructions as to the transfer or redemption of an<br />

underlying financial asset as well as to change entitlement holder's position to other<br />

form of security holding." 5 Finally, a purchaser of a security entitlement, who<br />

obtains control of it for value and without notice of any adverse claim to the security<br />

entitlement or the underlying financial asset, takes that security entitlement free<br />

from the adverse claim." 6<br />

Both UCC Article 8 and OSTA further provide for coherent choice of law rules<br />

to apply to the indirect holding system. In the direct holding system, a key factor in<br />

determining the governing law of a transaction is the location of the security. This<br />

location is not always easy to determine." 7 Furthermore, particularly in the context<br />

of globalization, the lex situs of the security may not fit the expectations of an<br />

entitlement holder and a securities intermediary located other than where the<br />

security is located. Indeed, as indicated, both Revised Article 8 and OSTA focus on<br />

the "security entitlement," and consequently, on the bilateral relationship between<br />

an entitlement holder and the securities intermediary. This, rather than the<br />

"security," or the link between an investor and the issuer, constitutes the foundation<br />

of the legal regime governing the indirect holding system. Consistently with this<br />

approach, the key factor in determining the governing law in the indirect holding<br />

system has been stated in UCC 8-110(b) and OSTA Section 45(1) to be the law of<br />

the securities intermediary's jurisdiction."' Such law is stated to govern the<br />

acquisition of a security entitlement from the securities intermediary, the respective<br />

rights and duties arising from a security entitlement, and rights of an adverse<br />

claimant. In the absence of a specific agreement, a "securities intermediary's<br />

jurisdiction" is the jurisdiction where the securities account is maintained." 9<br />

Finally, in conjunction with corresponding amendments to UCC Article 9 and<br />

to the Ontario Personal Property Security Act (OPPSA)' ° governing secured<br />

511; Ontario Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, § 105 (providing for the priority of entitlement<br />

holders over the securities intermediary's creditors, other than secured parties (of the securities<br />

intermediary) having "control" over the financial asset).<br />

113. U.C.C. § 8-504; Ontario Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, § 98.<br />

114. U.C.C. §§ 8-505 to 8-506; Ontario Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, §§ 99-100.<br />

115. U.C.C. §§ 8-507 to 8-508; Ontario Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, §§ 101-02.<br />

116. U.C.C. § 8-510; Ontario Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, § 104.<br />

117. See Geva, Consumer Liability, supra note 74.<br />

118. Cf. Hague Convention on the <strong>Law</strong> Applicable to Certain Rights in Respect of Securities Held<br />

with an Intermediary, July 5, 2006, http://hcch.e-vision.nl/indexen.php?act=conventions.pdf&cid=72; see<br />

also Bradley Crawford, The Hague "PRIMA" Convention: Choice of <strong>Law</strong> to Govern Recognition of<br />

Dispositions of Book-Based Securities in Cross Border Transactions, 38 Can. Bus. L.J. 157 (2003).<br />

119. U.C.C. § 8-110(e). The Ontario Securities Transfer Act states that if the law is not agreed upon,<br />

it is the law of the jurisdiction where the securities intermediary's office maintaining the particular<br />

securities account is located, as such office is identified by contract, or otherwise, in an account statement.<br />

Ontario Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, § 45(2). In the absence of any such identification, it is the<br />

law of the jurisdiction in which the chief executive office of the securities intermediary is located. Id.<br />

120. See Personal Property Security Act, R.S.O. 1990, ch. P.10, c. 8, §§ 123-141 (coming into force Jan.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 710 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 711<br />

transactions, rules applying to security interests in investment securities have been<br />

provided for. In general, as for any other form of personal property, a security<br />

interest in securities is to be created by agreement between the debtor and the<br />

secured party. A new collateral category, "investment property," was introduced to<br />

cover securities, security entitlements and security accounts."' Under UCC 9-314(a)<br />

and OPPSA Section 22.1, a security interest in investment property may be<br />

perfected 2 by "control."<br />

With respect to a security entitlement, "control" is achieved under UCC 8-<br />

106(d) and OSTA Section 25(1) by becoming an entitlement holder. Under both<br />

provisions, "control" may alternatively be achieved by the securities intermediary's<br />

agreement that it will comply with entitlement orders, namely, with directions to<br />

transfer or redeem the pertinent financial asset, originated by the secured party (or<br />

any other purchaser), without further consent of the entitlement holder. A third<br />

alternative under OSTA Section 25(1) as well as under a proposed addition to UCC<br />

8-106(d) is by the control of another person on behalf of the purchaser. Both UCC<br />

9-106(a) and OPPSA Section 1(2)(c) specifically incorporate UCC 8-106 and OSTA<br />

Section 25.<br />

Perfection by control is in line with the broad principle underlying UCC 8-106<br />

(as well as in effect OSTA Sections 23 to 26), under which "'[o]btaining control'<br />

means that the purchaser [including a secured party] has taken whatever steps are<br />

necessary, given the manner in which the securities are held, to place itself in a<br />

'<br />

position where it can have the securities sold, without further action by the owner.<br />

Both Article 8 and OSTA do not preclude perfection of a security interest in<br />

investment property other than by control;' and yet, under UCC. 9-328(1),<br />

"control" provides the utmost priority in investment property: "A security interest<br />

held by a secured party having control of investment property under Section 9-106<br />

has priority over a security interest held by a secured party that does not have<br />

control of the investment property."' 2 5 OPPSA Section 30.1 is to the same effect.<br />

1, 2007 as the most recent amendment to the OPPSA) [hereinafter Ontario Personal Property Security<br />

Act].<br />

121. U.C.C. § 9-102(a)(49) (encompassing "security[ies]," "security entitlement[s]," and "securities<br />

account[s]," as well as "commodity contract" and commodity account" under Article 8).<br />

122. In general, under both U.C.C. Article 9 and OPPSA, a "security interest" is an interest in<br />

personal property, created by agreement, securing payment of a debt or the performance of an obligation.<br />

Id. § 1-201(b)(35) & art. 9; Ontario Personal Property Security Act, R.S.O. 1990, ch. P.10, c. 8, § 1.<br />

"Collateral" is the property subject to the security interest. U.C.C. § 9-102(a)(12); Ontario Personal<br />

Property Security Act, R.S.O. 1990, ch. P.10, § 1. The "secured party" is the holder of a security interest.<br />

U.C.C. § 9-102(a)(12); Ontario Personal Property Security Act, R.S.O. 1990, ch. P.10, c. 8, § 1.<br />

"Perfection" denotes the completion of all required steps designed to protect the secured party from claims<br />

of third parties such as buyers from and creditors of the debtor. U.C.C. § 9-308; Ontario Personal Property<br />

Security Act, R.S.O. 1990, ch. P.10, c. 8, § 19. For the perfection of security interests in investment<br />

property other than by "control," see generally infra note 123.<br />

123. U.C.C. § 8-106, cmt. 1 (1994); Ontario Securities Transfer Act, S.O. 2006, ch. 8, §§ 23-26; see<br />

generally U.C.C. § 8-106(a)-(d) (2006) (offering various definitions of "control").<br />

124. See also Ontario Personal Property Security Act, R.S.O. 1990, ch. P.10, § 23 ("Registration<br />

perfects a security interest in any type of collateral."): id. § 22(3) ("[A] security interest in a certificated<br />

security in registered form is perfected by delivery when delivery of the certificated security occurs .<br />

U.C.C. §§ 9-310(a), 9-313(a) (paralleling Ontario Personal Property Security Act §§ 23, 22(3)).<br />

125. U.C.C. 9-328(1).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 711 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

V. EU PROPOSED LEGAL FRAMEWORK FOR A SINGLE PAYMENT<br />

MARKET<br />

A. Introduction<br />

In its proposal for a Directive on payment services in the internal market<br />

(Proposed Directive), the Commission of the European Communities (the<br />

Commission) purported to provide for "a harmonised legal framework" designed to<br />

create "a Single Payment Market where improved economies of scale and<br />

competition would help to reduce the cost of the payment system. ' 26 Being<br />

"complemented by industry's initiative for a Single Euro Payment Area (SEPA),<br />

aimed at integrating national payment infrastructures and payment products for the<br />

euro-zone," the Proposed Directive is designed to "establish a common framework<br />

for the Community payments market creating the conditions for integration and<br />

rationalisation of national payment systems.' ' 127 Focusing on electronic payments,<br />

and designed to "leave maximum room for self-regulation of industry," the Proposed<br />

Directive purports to "only harmonise what is necessary to overcome legal barriers<br />

28<br />

to a Single Market, avoiding regulating issues which would go beyond this matter.'<br />

<strong>State</strong>d otherwise, the measure will fall short of providing for a comprehensive<br />

payment law.<br />

The scope of the Proposed Directive is stated in Article 2(1) to "apply ... to<br />

business activities," referred to as "payment services," listed in the Annex, and<br />

"consisting in the execution of payment transactions on behalf of a natural or legal<br />

person . . . where at least one of the payment service providers is located in the<br />

Community."' 29 A "payment transaction" is defined to "consist in the act, initiated<br />

by the payer or the payee, of depositing, withdrawing or transferring funds 3 ' from a<br />

payer to a payee,' irrespective of any underlying obligations between the payment<br />

service users."' 32 "Payment services" listed in the Annex 3 are cash deposits and<br />

withdrawals in and from payment accounts;. execution of payment transactions in<br />

funds held on deposit in a payment account; execution of direct debits; execution of<br />

payment transactions through a payment card (or a similar device); execution of<br />

credit transfers (including standing orders); execution of payment transactions in<br />

funds covered by a credit line; execution of direct debits (including one-off direct<br />

126. Commission of the European Communities, Commission Proposal for a Directive of the<br />

European Parliament and of the Council on Payment Services in the Internal Market 2 (Dec. 1, 2005)<br />

[hereinafter Commission Proposal], available at http://eurlex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/site/en/com/2005/com2005_0603en01.pdL<br />

127. Id.<br />

128. Id. at 8.<br />

129. Id. art. 2(1).<br />

130. Id. art. 4(8) (defining "funds" as "cash, scriptural money and electronic money . .<br />

131. Id. art. 4(4)-(5) ("'[Player' means a natural or legal person who has the right of disposal of funds<br />

and who allows them to be transferred to a payee [and] 'payee' means a natural or legal person who is the<br />

intended final recipient of funds which have been the subject of a payment transaction .... ").<br />

132. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 2 (describing what constitutes a "payment<br />

transaction"); id. art. 4(6) (including payer and payee as payment service users).<br />

133. The Annex is quite disorganized and repetitive. For example, the terms "payment card," "direct<br />

debit," and "credit transfer" are each enumerated at least twice. Id. at 54.<br />

134. Id. art. 4(7) ("'Payment account' means an account held in the name of a payment service user<br />

which is used exclusively for payment transactions.").<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 712 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 713<br />

debits)' 3 ; issuing of payment cards; execution of payment transactions in e-money;<br />

money remittance services in funds accepted for the sole purpose of carrying out the<br />

payment transaction; and execution of certain payment transactions by any means of<br />

communication at a distance such as mobile telephones or other digital or IT<br />

devices. '<br />

Article 3 deals with the outer limits of the Proposed Directive. Thereunder,<br />

cash payments, collections, delivery and transport, as well as certain cash refunds 137<br />

are specifically excluded. Also excluded from the coverage of the Proposed<br />

Directive are change of foreign currency in the form of cash-to-cash operations;<br />

paper checks, vouchers, traveller's checks and promissory notes;' 38 payment<br />

transactions carried out within a payment or security clearing and settlement system;<br />

payment processing services; payment by instruments which are not redeemable<br />

within a limited network or affiliated service providers; certain payment transactions<br />

executed by means of a mobile telephone or any other digital or IT device;' 39 and<br />

payment transactions carried out between payment service providers as well as tied<br />

agents or subsidiaries.'<br />

Coverage of payment transactions by any means of communication at a<br />

distance requires further analysis. The "Execution of a payment transaction by any<br />

means of communication at a distance such as mobile telephones or other IT<br />

devices" is a payment service listed in the Annex and is thus covered by the<br />

Proposed Directive, "where the service provider operating the telecommunication or<br />

IT system or network,"<br />

* "is facilitating the payment of goods or services that are not digital goods<br />

or electronic communication services and so are provided through the<br />

device itself"; or<br />

* "simply arranges a transfer of funds for the payment of digital goods or<br />

electronic communication services provided through the device, without<br />

any other intervention in the service provided."''<br />

Conversely, under Article 3(j), "Payment transactions executed by means of a<br />

mobile telephone or any other digital or IT device" is to be excluded from the<br />

Proposed Directive, "where all the following conditions are met":<br />

135. "Direct debit," "credit transfers," and "payment card" are not defined in the Directive.<br />

136. Although the "execution of payment transactions ... at a distance" are generally covered by the<br />

Directive, an exception exists in Article 3(j), as discussed below. Id. ann. at 54.<br />

137. Id. art. 3(d) (excluding "cash refunds provided by the payee to the payer after a payment<br />

transaction following an explicit request by the payment service user made just before the execution of a<br />

payment transaction through a payment card and completely independent of the cost of the good or<br />

services purchased .... ).<br />

138. See id. at 13 ("This [proposed] Directive should not apply to payment transactions made in cash<br />

or to those based on paper cheques since, by their nature, they cannot be processed as efficiently as other<br />

means of payment, in particular electronic payments."). In light of Part I of this Paper, the reasoning<br />

underlying this statement ought to be taken with a grain of salt, at least insofar as checks are concerned.<br />

139. For the conditions under which payment transactions executed by mobile phone or digital or<br />

other IT devices are covered under the Annex and excluded under Article 3(j), see next paragraph.<br />

140. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 4(16) ('"ITlied agent' means a natural or legal person<br />

which acts on behalf of a payment institution in carrying out payment services ....<br />

141. Emphasis added<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 713 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

(i)<br />

(ii)<br />

"the service provider operating the telecommunication or IT system<br />

or network is closely involved in the development of the digital<br />

goods or electronic communication services provided"; and<br />

"the goods and service cannot be delivered in the absence of the<br />

service provider."<br />

These provisions distinguish between "digital goods or electronic<br />

communication services" (digital products) and other goods and services (non-digital<br />

products). Language and rationale of these provisions are not entirely clear. For<br />

example, for the Proposed Directive to apply, why does the language quoted in the<br />

first bullet limited to non-digital products provided "through the device itself"? And<br />

if they are not provided "through the device itself," can they still be covered under<br />

another more general "payment service"? Second, exclusion under Article 3(j) is<br />

limited to digital products covered under the second bulleted quoted language. Yet,<br />

the rationale of this exception is not self explanatory; moreover, there is a gray area<br />

between the second bulleted quoted language (under which service is covered) and<br />

the exclusion under Article 3(j); thus, any "intervention in the service provided,"<br />

beyond the arrangement of the funds transfer, will exempt the transaction from<br />

coverage under the second bulleted quoted language; at the same time, to fall within<br />

the exclusion under Article 3(j), the service provider's involvement must exceed<br />

mere intervention; he must be "closely involved in the development of the digital<br />

goods or electronic communication services provided."<br />

Title I of the Proposed Directive provides for subject matter, scope and<br />

definitions. It is followed by three substantive components. First, Title II covers<br />

payment service providers. Second, Title III deals with transparency of conditions<br />

for payment services. Third, Title IV governs rights and obligations in relation to the<br />

provision and use of payment services. Under Article 2, both Titles III and IV are<br />

limited to payment transactions of up to EUR 50,000; stated otherwise, they provide<br />

for payment law for retail funds transfers. While large-value payments are thus<br />

excluded, payments of up to EUR 50,000 taking place on wholesale transfer systems,<br />

particularly targeted at large-value payments, remain nevertheless covered.' 42 The<br />

three substantive components are followed by Titles V and VI dealing with<br />

amendments, Payment Committee, and final provisions.<br />

The ensuing discussion outlines the statutory scheme set out in the three<br />

substantive parts, namely Titles II, III and IV, covering licensing, transparency, and<br />

transaction rights and obligations.<br />

B. Licensing of Non-Bank Payment Service Providers 3<br />

Title II establishes a legal framework for a single license for all providers of<br />

payment services which are not connected to taking deposits or issuing e-money, and<br />

regulated under existing EU directives.'" Payment service providers falling into this<br />

residuary category are referred to in the Preamble and the head-note to Chapter 1 of<br />

142. Id. at 13 ("[P]ayment[s] above this amount are not generally processed [in] the same way, are<br />

often channelled through different networks and are submitted to different technical and legal procedures<br />

that should be maintained.").<br />

143. Cf. UNIF. MONEY SERVICES ACT art. 2 (2001).<br />

144. See generally Council Directive 2000/12, 2000 O.J. (L 126) 1; Council Directive 2000/46, 2000 O.J.<br />

(L 275) 39.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 714 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 715<br />

Title II as "payment institutions," which otherwise, are not defined in the Proposed<br />

Directive. Title 11 is designed to "create a level-playing field, instil more competition<br />

in national markets and reflect market developments in recent years, triggering<br />

market entry of a new generation of providers." '45 To that end it is further designed<br />

to harmonize market access, also with the view of facilitating "the gradual migration<br />

of . . . providers from the unofficial economy to the official sector. 14 6 In the<br />

language of Paragraph 9 of the Preamble:<br />

The conditions for the granting and maintenance of authorisation of<br />

payment institutions should include prudential requirements<br />

proportionate to the operational and financial risks faced by such bodies in<br />

the course of their business. Those requirements should reflect the fact<br />

that payment institutions engage in more specialised and restricted<br />

activities, thus generating risks that are much narrower and easier to<br />

monitor and control than those that arise across the spectrum [or deposittaking]<br />

credit institutions. In particular, payment institutions should be<br />

prohibited from accepting deposits from users and permitted to use only<br />

funds accepted from users for rendering payment services. 4 7 Provision<br />

should be made for client funds to be kept separate from the payment<br />

institution's funds for other business activities."' Payment institutions<br />

should also be made subject to effective anti-money laundering and antiterrorist<br />

financing requirements. 4 9<br />

Authorization is to be valid in all Member <strong>State</strong>s. 5 '<br />

However, to prevent the<br />

forcing out into the "black economy" of those unable "to meet the full range of<br />

conditions for authorisation as payment institutions," provision is made for the<br />

registration "of payment institutions while not applying all of the conditions for<br />

authorisation," but only as long as derogation is limited to the provision of payment<br />

services within the Member <strong>State</strong> of registration and is "subject . . . to strict<br />

requirements relating to volume of transactions and importance for the public<br />

interest.". 5 '<br />

Activities permitted to payment institutions are enumerated in Article 10(1).<br />

They consist of (i)<br />

the provision of payment services; (ii) the provision of operational<br />

and related ancillary services such as the guaranteeing of the execution of payment<br />

transactions, foreign exchange services, safekeeping activities, and storage and<br />

processing of data; and (iii) accessing and operating payment systems.. 2 for the<br />

145. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, at 7.<br />

146. Id.<br />

147. "[Flunds received by payment institutions from payment service users with a view to the<br />

provision of payment services shall not constitute a deposit or other repayable funds within the meaning of<br />

Article 3 of Directive 2000/12/EC, or electronic money within the meaning of Directive 2000/46/EC." Id.<br />

art. 10(1). The former Directive governs deposit-taking by credit institutions and the latter governs<br />

electronic money institutions. See supra note 144.<br />

148. Article 10 codifies the separation of payment service users funds from non-payment service<br />

funds. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 10(2).<br />

149. Id. at 12.<br />

150. Id. art. 6.<br />

151. Id. at 12-13; see infra note 160.<br />

152. See Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 4(3) ("'[P]ayment system' means a funds transfer<br />

system with formal and standardised arrangements and common rules for the processing, clearing and/or<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 715 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

purpose of transferring, clearing and settling funds, including any instruments and<br />

procedures relating to the systems. Under Article 10(3), all such activities "shall be<br />

non-exclusive and shall not be restricted to payment services, having regard to the<br />

53<br />

applicable national and Community law.'<br />

Specific provisions deal with the authorization process;' 5 " govern the use of<br />

third-parties by payment institutions; ' require record-keeping,' 56 registration of<br />

head office 57 and professional secrecy;' 58 provide for supervision; " and regulate the<br />

derogation from authorization and its substitution by registration requirements.'6<br />

Finally, equality of treatment throughout the Community between the different<br />

categories of payment service providers is provided for. 16 '<br />

C. Transparency of Conditions for Payment Services<br />

Title III governs transparency of conditions for payment services for payment<br />

transactions throughout the Community that do not exceed EUR 50,000.162 It is<br />

stated to aim at providing users with standardized "high level of clear information"<br />

enabling them "to make well-informed choices and be able to shop around within<br />

the EU" and yet to ensure that "[m]icro payments should be a cheap and easy-to-use<br />

alternative in the case of low-priced goods and services and should not be<br />

overburdened by excessive requirements."' 63<br />

Title III has separate rules for single payment transactions (Articles 24-28) and<br />

for framework contracts (Articles 29-38). Common provisions (Articles 39-40) cover<br />

the selection of currency. A "framework contract" is defined in Article 29 to refer to<br />

an agreement which "commits a payment service provider to execute in the future<br />

successive payment transactions or individual payment transactions on the order of<br />

the payer if the agreed conditions are met."' ' No requirements are laid out as to<br />

settlement of payment transactions ....<br />

153. Id. art. 10(3).<br />

154. Id. arts. 5-9.<br />

155. Id. arts. 11-12.<br />

156. Id. art. 13.<br />

157. Id. art. 14.<br />

158. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 17.<br />

159. Id. arts. 15-16.<br />

160. Id. arts. 21-22. Derogation is where registration is necessary for the effective implementation of<br />

anti-money laundering and terrorist financing rules and mechanisms, for an institution whose business<br />

activity generates "a total amount of funds outstanding which were accepted for the provision of payment<br />

services and which does not exceed EUR 5 million on average over a month and EUR 6 million at any<br />

given point in time," and which plays a vital role in financial intermediation, providing access to payment<br />

services for underprivileged social groups. Id. art. 21(1). A person benefiting from the exception shall be<br />

treated as a payment institution but may provide payment services only within the Member <strong>State</strong> of<br />

registration and may be permitted to engage only in certain of the activities listed in Article 10. Id. art.<br />

21(2).<br />

161. Id. art. 23 ("[R]ules on access to and operation of payment systems shall be objective and<br />

proportionate and shall not inhibit access more than is necessary to safeguard against specific risks and to<br />

protect the financial safety of the payment system.").<br />

162. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, arts. 2, 24-40; see also id. art. 84 (providing for the repeal<br />

of Council Directive 97/5, 1997 O.J. (L 43) 25).<br />

163. Id. at 13-14; see also id. art. 38(1) (defining "micro payment" as one not exceeding 50 Euro).<br />

164. Id. art. 29.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 716 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 717<br />

either the medium in which such a contract is to be contained or as to whether the<br />

contract must be express.<br />

There is some overlap in disclosure requirements for both single payment<br />

transactions and framework contracts. For both, conditions are to be "set out in<br />

easily understandable words and in a clear and readable form," "on paper or on<br />

another durable medium, ' and "in good time before the payment service user is<br />

bound .... ."'6 In each case, 67 conditions consist of description of respective<br />

obligations and liabilities which include information or unique identifier' 68 to be<br />

provided by user in order for a payment order' 60 to be properly executed; execution<br />

time; and where applicable or appropriate, conditions such as safekeeping<br />

requirements for and risks associated with a payment verification instrument,' 70 and<br />

how to notify the service provider in case of loss or theft of the instrument.<br />

Conditions to be disclosed further consist of a clear reference to the point of time of<br />

acceptance of a payment order; 7 ' pertinent charges and "where applicable," relevant<br />

exchange rate; indication as to the governing law and competent court; indication of<br />

the redress and complaint procedure; and "an indication of where any other<br />

information may be made available and be consulted."<br />

In addition to such common disclosures for both categories, for a single<br />

payment transaction specific disclosure requirements are set out in Article 26(1).171<br />

They address liability for the execution of the payment transaction, "information to<br />

be provided in accordance with Directive 2005/. . ./EC,"' 173 and the availability of<br />

appropriate funds. 74 By the same token, and in addition to the common disclosures<br />

165. "'[D/urable medium' means any instrument which enables information addressed personally to<br />

the payment service user to be stored in a manner accessible for future reference for a period of time<br />

adequate to the purposes of the information and which allows the unchanged reproduction of the<br />

information stored; in particular, durable medium covers printouts by account printers, floppy disks, CD-<br />

ROMs, DVDs and hard drives of personal computers on which electronic mail is stored but excludes<br />

internet sites, unless such sites meet the criteria specified in the first sentence of this point." Id. art. 4(19).<br />

166. Id. arts. 25(1), 26; see also id. arts. 30(1), 32 (describing the communication of conditions to the<br />

payment service user with regard to framework contracts).<br />

167. See Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 26(1), 31(1).<br />

168. Id. art. 4(15) ("'[U]nique identifier' means the information specified by the payment service<br />

provider and to be provided by the payment service user to identify unambiguously the other payment<br />

service user involved in a payment transaction, and consisting of the IBAN (International Bank Account<br />

Number), the BIC (Bank Identifier Code), a bank account number, a card number or a name .... ").<br />

169. Id. art. 4(10) ("'[Payment order' means any instruction by a payer or payee to his payment<br />

service provider requesting the execution of a payment transaction .... ").<br />

170. Id. art. 4(17) ("'[P]ayment verification instrument' means any personalised device(s) and/or set of<br />

procedures used by the payment service user in order to enable the payment service provider to<br />

authenticate a payment order. If it is not provided by the payment service provider, the payment service<br />

provider and the payment service user may agree on the use of any other instrument for the authentication<br />

of payment orders which may also serve other purposes .... "); id. art. 4(13) ("'[A]uthentication' means a<br />

procedure which allows the payment service provider to verify that the user issuing the payment order is<br />

authorised to do so .... ").<br />

171. Id. art. 54 (time of acceptance is established only after the payment service provider has received,<br />

authenticated, and explicitly or implicitly accepted the obligation to execute the payment order).<br />

172. Commission Proposal, supra note 126. art. 26(1).<br />

173. See id. art. 26(1)(a)(v) (the blank reference ought to be taken as referring to a directive in<br />

preparation).<br />

174. Id. art. 4(9) ("'[A]vailability offinds' means that the funds on a payment account may be used by<br />

the payment service user without fees being charged .... ").<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 717 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

set out above, for a framework contract specific disclosure obligations are set out in<br />

Article 31(1)." 7 " They relate to the technical requirements with respect to user's<br />

equipment, termination rights, blocking of a payment verification instrument in case<br />

of suspicion of fraud, and spending ceilings. For a framework contract, explicit<br />

information on execution time and charges is to be disclosed before the execution of<br />

each payment transaction.176<br />

For each payment transaction, whether it is single or pursuant to a framework<br />

contract, subsequent to the acceptance of payment order for execution, the payment<br />

service provider is mandated 17 7 to make available to the payer a reference enabling<br />

the identification of the payment transaction, "where appropriate" information<br />

relating to the payee, amount of payment as well as of fees and charges, and "where<br />

relevant" exchange rate. Subsequent to making funds, received for the payee,<br />

available to him, the payment service provider is required 17 to make a similar<br />

disclosure to the payee, 179 though obviously with information as to the payer<br />

replacing information as to the payee. For a framework contract specific provisions<br />

are made in Articles 33 and 34 to govern changes in contractual provisions and<br />

termination.<br />

Under Article 38, disclosure requirements are substantially reduced in<br />

connection with "a [framework] contract concerning payments where no individual<br />

payment can exceed EUR 50 . . .,. In a case of a contract for such "micro<br />

payments," "the payment service provider shall communicate to the payment service<br />

user ... only the main characteristics of the payment service to be provided, the way<br />

in which it can be used and all charges applicable.''. Further required information is<br />

to be provided "in an easily accessible manner."" Subsequent to the execution of<br />

such a payment transaction, a service provider is to communicate "at least a<br />

reference enabling the ... user to identify the payment transaction, the amount...<br />

and the fees. ,183<br />

D. Rights and Obligations of Users and Providers of Payment Services<br />

Title IV provides for substantive law for major aspects of payment transactions<br />

not exceeding EUR 50,000. It covers the authorization of payment transactions, the<br />

execution of payment transactions, data protection, and penalties and procedures for<br />

settlement disputes.<br />

Authorization of payment transactions is governed by Chapter 1 consisting of<br />

Articles 41-53. Article 2(1) defines a "payment transaction" to "consist in the act,<br />

initiated by the payer or the payee, of depositing, withdrawing or transferring funds<br />

175. Id. art. 31(1).<br />

176. See id. art. 35.<br />

177. See id. art. 27 (single payment transaction); see also id. art. 36 (payment transaction executed<br />

pursuant to a framework contract).<br />

178. See Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 28 (single payment transaction); see also id. art. 37<br />

(payment transaction executed pursuant to a framework contract).<br />

179. See id. arts. 25(1), 26(2), 30(1), 31(2) (disclosure requirements).<br />

180. Id. art. 38.<br />

181. Id.<br />

182. Id.<br />

183. Id. Quare as to whether these requirements are specific enough to guide payment service<br />

providers as to what they ought to do.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 718 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 719<br />

from a payer to a payee . . ."; this includes both payer-initiated "credit-push" and<br />

payee-initiated "debit-pull" transfers." Article 41. however equates authorization<br />

only with the payer's consent, which is obviously required also for "debit-pull"<br />

withdrawals by the payee from the payer's account. Arguably, then, Chapter 1 is<br />

concerned only with the payer's authorization, for payment transactions initiated by<br />

either the payer or the payee.<br />

Article 42 envisages that an authorization for a payment transaction is to be<br />

subject to a procedure agreed between the payer and the payer's payment service<br />

provider, that it may be communicated directly to the payer's payment service<br />

provider or indirectly via the payee, and that it may (though not must) be<br />

transmitted by means of a "payment verification instrument....85 As well,<br />

authorization must specify the exact amount and identify the payee; it also must be<br />

in an amount expected from a reasonable payer in that position.' 86<br />

The following summary outlines the exposure to payment transactions<br />

purported to emanate under the authority of a payment service user as a payer:<br />

1.) Under Article 41, a payer is bound only for payment transactions explicitly<br />

authorized by him. 87 Otherwise, "a payment transaction shall be considered to be<br />

unauthorised." Curiously, there is no provision for implied or apparent authority.'"<br />

Authorization may be given either prior or subsequent to the execution of the<br />

payment transaction. Under Article 43, where it is transmitted by means of a<br />

payment verification instrument it may vary with respect to prescribed spending<br />

limits.<br />

2.) A payment service user may further be liable under Article 50(1) for the loss<br />

up to EUR 150 "resulting from the use of a lost or stolen payment verification<br />

9<br />

instrument' and occurring before he has fulfilled his obligation to notify his<br />

184. In a credit transfer, such as a direct payroll, benefit deposit, or a wire transfer, the payer's<br />

instructions are communicated to the payer's bank directly, so as to 'push' funds to the payee's account.<br />

Conversely, in a debit transfer, such as the deposit of a check for collection or the collection of insurance<br />

premiums, loan installments, or taxes, the payee, acting under the payer's authority, instructs the payee's<br />

bank to 'pull' or collect funds from the payer's account. In a credit transfer, the banking operation<br />

commences with a debit to the payer's account. In contrast, in a debit transfer, the banking operation<br />

typically commences with a credit, albeit temporary and provisional (pending collection from the payer), to<br />

the payee's account. See, e.g., Benjamin Geva, International Funds Transfers: Mechanisms and <strong>Law</strong>s, in<br />

CROSS-BORDER ELECTRONIC BANKING: CHALLENGES AND OPPORTUNITIES 1, 2-3 (Chris Reed, Ian<br />

Walden & Laura Edgar eds., 2nd ed. 2000).<br />

185. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 4(17) ("'[Playment verification instrument' means any<br />

personalised device(s) and/or set of procedures used by the payment service user in order to enable the<br />

payment service provider to authenticate a payment order. If it is not provided by the payment service<br />

provider, the payment service provider and the payment service user may agree on the use of any other<br />

instrument for the authentication of payment orders which may also serve other purposes .... ").<br />

186. Id. arts. 52-53 (governing refund for authorized payments that do not meet these requirements,<br />

for other than large enterprises). Per Preamble paragraph 23, "refund rights should not affect the liability<br />

of the payer vis-A-vis the payee .... " Id. at 14.<br />

187. I follow the language of the Proposed Directive which uses "he" and "him" to include "she" or<br />

"her."<br />

188. As a matter of agency law, authority can be actual or apparent. Actual authority may be express<br />

or implied. See, e.g., BLACK'S LAW DICTIONARY, supra note 97, at 67, 142.<br />

189. A Member <strong>State</strong> may reduce that maximum amount for payment service providers authorized by<br />

it. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 719 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

payment service provider" of the loss or theft. 90 Under Article 46(b), the obligation<br />

is "to notify . . . without undue delay on becoming aware of loss, theft or<br />

misappropriation of the payment verification instrument or of its unauthorised<br />

1<br />

use.'' Presumably then, the payer is not liable for loss occurring prior to learning<br />

the loss or theft since until then he has not been in breach of his notification<br />

obligation.<br />

3.) Notwithstanding no. 2 above, the payment service user "shall bear all the<br />

losses on unauthorised transactions if he incurred them by acting fraudulently or<br />

with gross negligence with regard to his obligations under Article 46. ' 92 It is<br />

noteworthy that Article 45 requires the user to keep safe security features of a<br />

payment verification instrument and use it in accordance with the terms governing<br />

its issuing and use, and to give timely notification of loss or theft. It is however not<br />

explicitly stated that loss caused by breach of such duties, other than that of the duty<br />

to promptly notify covered by Article 46(b), is to be allocated to the payment service<br />

user.<br />

4.) Under Article 49, the payment service provider is to refund the payment<br />

service user "forthwith" the amount of an unauthorized payment transaction;<br />

presumably this applies to any amount for which the user is not responsible under<br />

no. 2 and 3 above. The provision goes on to state: "Further financial compensation<br />

may be determined in accordance with the law applicable to the contract concluded<br />

between the payment service provider and the payment service user.<br />

'<br />

5.) Where a payment service user disputes an alleged authorization, under<br />

Article 48(1), "the payment service provider is to provide at least evidence that the<br />

payment transaction was authenticated,' 94 accurately recorded, entered in the<br />

95<br />

accounts and not affected by a technical breakdown or some other deficiency.'<br />

Presumably, such facts give rise to a presumption of authorization. Arguably, in this<br />

context, the payment service provider is to prove compliance with obligations<br />

fastened on him with respect to the payment verification instrument under Article<br />

47. These obligations are to protect the security features of a payment verification<br />

instrument, to refrain from sending unsolicited payment verification instruments,<br />

and to ensure that appropriate means are available to enable users to make<br />

notification.<br />

6.) To rebut this presumption, the payment transaction user is required under<br />

Article 48(2), to "provide factual information or elements to allow the presumption<br />

that he could not have authorised the payment transaction and that he did not act<br />

fraudulently or with gross negligence with regard to the obligations incumbent upon<br />

him ....,,196<br />

7.) In any event, under Article 48(3), "the use of a payment verification<br />

instrument recorded by the payment service provider shall not, of itself, be sufficient<br />

190. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 50(1).<br />

191. Id. arts. 45(1), 46(b). However, under Article 50(4), the payment service user who has not acted<br />

fraudulently is dissolved of any responsibility if the payment service provider "does not provide adequate<br />

means for the notification ...... Id. art. 50(4). For the payment service provider's record-keeping<br />

obligations, see id. art. 44.<br />

192. Id. art. 50(2); see also id. art. 50(3).<br />

193. Id. art. 49.<br />

194. For the definition of "Authentication," see supra note 170.<br />

195. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 48(1).<br />

196. Id. art. 48(2).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 720 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 721<br />

to establish either that the payment was authorised by the payment service user or<br />

that the payment service user acted fraudulently or with gross negligence ....<br />

Two exemptions are provided for in Article 51. First, under Article 51(2),<br />

protections against unauthorized use are limited in the case of e-money.<br />

Particularly, responsibility for unauthorized use continues notwithstanding of giving<br />

notice of theft or loss, as long as payment service provider is technically incapable to<br />

freeze or prevent further spending of the e-money stored on the electronic device.<br />

Second, Article 51(1) exempts large enterprises " ' from Articles 49-50, dealing with<br />

respective liabilities of provider and user for losses in respect of unauthorized<br />

payment transactions. The exemption is however unclear and not self-explanatory.<br />

So far as Article 49 is concerned, does the exemption mean that large enterprises are<br />

not entitled to a refund for unauthorized payments? This is absurd. Does it only<br />

mean they are not entitled to refund "forthwith"? Exemption from Article 50 is<br />

even more enigmatic; does it mean that large enterprise is released from the EUR<br />

150 minimum liability for no-fault unauthorized use? Presumably, per Preamble<br />

Paragraph 22, the intent has been to exempt large enterprises from the entire<br />

unauthorized use loss allocation scheme, "since such enterprises are normally in a<br />

position to assess the risk of fraud and take countervailing measures."' 9 Arguably,<br />

the theory may also be that large enterprises are in a position to bargain with<br />

payment institutions for a favorable loss allocation scheme.<br />

Chapter 2 of Title IV, consisting of Articles 54-74 deals with various aspects<br />

relating to the execution of a payment transaction. It is divided to three Sections.<br />

Section 1, consisting of Articles 54-58, deals with payment orders, fees, and amount<br />

transferred. Section 2, consisting of Articles 59-64, deals with execution time.<br />

Section 3, consisting of Articles 65-70, deals with availability of funds and liability.<br />

For all these stages and aspects, the point of acceptance is of fundamental<br />

importance. Section 1 identifies for a payment order, the point of both the loss of its<br />

revocability by the payment service user, 2°° as well as arguably, of the loss the refusal<br />

right by the payment service provider."" Either loss occurs upon the acceptance by<br />

the payment service provider. As well, as will be seen further below, under Section<br />

2, permissible execution time is as of the acceptance of the payment order. Finally,<br />

under Section 3, upon acceptance, a payment service provider incurs strict liability<br />

for non-execution or defective execution.<br />

"Acceptance" is, however, not defined; presumably it denotes the binding<br />

agreement of the payment service provider to carry out the payment order, which, in<br />

turn, is defined in Article 4(10) to mean "any instruction by a payer or payee to his<br />

payment service provider requesting the execution of a payment transaction."<br />

Under Article 54, acceptance of a payment order covered by a payer's authorization<br />

197. Id. art. 48(3).<br />

198. Defined by reference to Articles 1 and 2(1) and (3) of Title I of the Annex to Recommendation<br />

2003/361/EC. Id. art. 51(1).<br />

199. Id. at 14.<br />

200. See id. art. 56 ("[T]he payment service provider and the payment service user may agree on a<br />

date of irrevocability that falls within the three working days preceding the point in time of acceptance for<br />

the order.").<br />

201. See Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 55 (providing some limits and requiring prompt<br />

advice "in any case, within three working days" of the refusal and related information). Unlike Article 56.<br />

Article 55 is not explicit as to the loss of the right of refusal upon the acceptance of the payment order.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 721 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

may not occur prior to its receipt, complete authentication, 2 ° and the explicit or<br />

implicit acceptance of the obligation to execute the payment transaction ordered, by<br />

the payment service provider. Making acceptance contingent in part on the<br />

occurrence of explicit or implicit acceptance is however an awkward way to state<br />

that acceptance may be either explicit or implicit; the provision thus goes on to state<br />

that acceptance (whether explicit or implicit) may not occur prior to the receipt of<br />

the payment order and its authentication. Article 54(1) further states that<br />

acceptance "shall not be later than the point in time when the payment service<br />

provider starts to execute the payment transaction"; presumably then, the<br />

commencement of "execution" is the mode par excellence for an implicit acceptance.<br />

Further under Article 54(2), where the payment transaction is "electronically<br />

initiated, 2 °3 the payment service provider is to inform the payment service user of<br />

the acceptance, "without undue delay and, in any case, before the end of the next<br />

working day after the point in time of acceptance .... ,2 Such notice is however to<br />

be given after the acceptance, and is not part of the acceptance itself.<br />

For an intra-Community transfer, and in the absence of currency exchange, fees<br />

are to be charged to each payment service user only by his payment service provider;<br />

intermediaries are precluded from deducting fees from the amount transferred.<br />

Section 2, consisting of Article 60-64, deals with execution time. Article 59<br />

states that the Section applies "only if the payment service providers of both the<br />

payer and the payee are located in the Community" and not to apply to micro<br />

payments, presumably, those of EUR 50 and below. 2 0 6 Limits are set for both payer<br />

and payee initiated payment transactions; per Article 64 such limits may be<br />

shortened for "purely national payment transactions., 20 7<br />

For both payment transactions initiated by the payer and payment transactions<br />

initiated by or through the payee, under both Articles 61 and 62, execution is to be<br />

completed not later than at the end of the first working day following the point of<br />

time acceptance. Execution is completed typically by having the amount credited to<br />

the payee's account, and in the case of a payment transaction initiated by or<br />

through the payee, also by having the funds made available to the payee. 2 9<br />

Unfortunately, there is no provision explicitly linking the completion of the<br />

execution of a payment transaction initiated by or through the payee with the<br />

posting of an irrevocable and final debit to the payer's account.<br />

In any event, this one-day time limit for the execution of a payment transaction,<br />

rationalized on the need "to improve the efficiency of payments throughout the<br />

Community," 2 ' ° is, however, partially compromised as follows:<br />

202. For the definition of "Authentication," see supra note 170.<br />

203. Neither execution nor electronic initiation is defined.<br />

204. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 54(2).<br />

205. See id. arts. 57-58.<br />

206. Id. art. 59; see supra notes 154, 183-183 and accompanying text.<br />

207. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 64.<br />

208. Though, per Article 62, the deadlines remain effective even in the absence of payee's payment<br />

account with the payment service provider. Per Article 63, the one-day execution deadline also applies to<br />

credit given for cash deposits by the payment service user to his own account.<br />

209. <strong>State</strong>d otherwise, provisional credit will not satisfy the deadline requirement.<br />

210. Id. at 15.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 722 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 723<br />

For payment transactions initiated by the payer, "up to I January 2010, a payer<br />

and his payment service provider may agree on a period no longer than three<br />

days." , 2 1<br />

For payment transactions initiated by the payer, and for all payment<br />

transactions initiated by or through the payee, an explicit agreement between the<br />

initiator and his payment service provider may agree on a longer (or in theory,<br />

shorter) execution period.<br />

For a payment transaction initiated by or through the payee, his payment<br />

service provider has the option of refusing to release the funds to the payee, but is to<br />

inform the payee of the refusal within the time for execution. Presumably, this is<br />

designed to provide for the case of dishonor by the payer's payment service<br />

provider.<br />

Section 3, consisting of Articles 65-70, deals with funds availability and liability.<br />

So far as liability is concerned, it covers misdescription of payee and liability for nonexecution<br />

or defective execution.<br />

In principle, under Article 65, funds are to be become available to the payee, at<br />

no additional fees, as soon as they are credited to the payee's account. No provision<br />

is made for provisional credit to the payee's account in connection with debit-pull<br />

transfers initiated by the payee. Similarly, funds cease to become available to the<br />

payer once they are debited to the payer's account. The point in time at which an<br />

account is debited or credited is respectively the debit value date for the payer's<br />

payment account and the credit value date for the payee's payment account. 212<br />

Article 66(1) appears to protect a payee's payment service provider that<br />

executed a payment order "in accordance with the unique identifier" 3 provided by<br />

the user." ' An account number, or more specifically an IBAN, 2 5 specified as the<br />

unique identifier "take[s] precedence over the name of the payee if it is provided<br />

additionally. 216 These absolute statements are however immediately qualified, since<br />

the payment service provider is required "where possible" to verify the consistency<br />

of the account number with the name. Certainly, the provision is not to be taken to<br />

protect a service provider that either neglected that duty or that credited an account<br />

knowing it does not belong to the named payee." 7<br />

Under Article 66(2), "If the unique identifier provided by the payment service<br />

user is incorrect, the payment service provider shall not be liable for the nonexecution<br />

or defective execution of the transaction." It is not clear however whether<br />

"incorrect" includes "inconsistent" under Article 66(1) and if so what effect has the<br />

verification duty as well as its fulfillment on the defense available to the service<br />

provider under Article 66(2). In any event, notwithstanding this defense, a payment<br />

service provider that misdirected payments on the basis of an incorrect unique<br />

identifier is required to "make a bona fide effort to recover the funds involved in the<br />

211. Id. art. 60(1).<br />

212. Id. art. 65.<br />

213. See supra note 168 and accompanying text (defining "unique identifier").<br />

214. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 66.<br />

215. IBAN is an acronym for the International Bank Account Number. Id. art. 4(15).<br />

216. Id. art. 66(1).<br />

217. id. art. 66.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 723 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

payment transaction." 2 8 No provision is made for errors in the amount of a payment<br />

transaction.<br />

Subject to that, under Article 67, upon acceptance, a payment service provider<br />

incurs strict liability "for the non-execution or defective execution of a payment<br />

transaction" that cover also additional fees and interest charges. Per Article 69,<br />

additional compensation under national law applicable to the contract between the<br />

payment service provider and user is not precluded. There is, however, no provision<br />

for privity nor for its dispensation; no chain of liability is provided for so that it is not<br />

clear who is liable to whom. There is also no express provision for money-back<br />

guarantee, namely, for the refund obligation of the payer's payment service<br />

provider, in case execution has not been properly completed. At the same time,<br />

liability is excused under Article 70 in case of force majeure or "where a payment<br />

service provider is bound by other legal obligations expressly covered by national or<br />

Community legislation, such as money laundering and anti-terrorist financing<br />

provisions. '' " 9 Under Article 68, where the payment service provider of the payee is<br />

not located in a Member <strong>State</strong>, "the payment service provider of the payer shall be<br />

liable for the execution of the payment transactions only until the funds reach the<br />

payee's payment service provider."" 2 Quare as to the scope of the responsibility of<br />

the payer's payment service provider beyond that point, in the case in which the<br />

payee's payment service provider is located in a Member <strong>State</strong>. It may also not be<br />

clear as to whether in any event the payer's payment service provider's responsibility<br />

under Article 67 amounts to a money-back guarantee. At least so far as the second<br />

question is concerned, the language appears to be broad enough to cover an<br />

unlimited money-back guarantee obligation of the payment service provider of the<br />

221<br />

payer.<br />

Chapter 3 of Title IV dealing with data protection consists exclusively of Article<br />

71 which permits the processing of personal data by payment systems and payment<br />

service providers "when this is necessary to safeguard the prevention, investigation,<br />

2<br />

detection and prosecution of payment fraud. The effect is to provide for an<br />

exemption from rules governing data protection.<br />

Finally, Chapter 5 of Title IV, consisting of Articles 72-75, deals with penalties<br />

and dispute settlement. It provides a framework for setting up complaint<br />

procedures, penalties for violations, enforcement by competent authorities, and outof-court<br />

redress.<br />

218. Id. art. 66(2)<br />

219. Id. art. 70.<br />

220. Id. art. 68.<br />

221. This is to be contrasted with the 12,500 limit to the qualified money-back guarantee obligation<br />

under Council Directive 97/5, art. 8, 1997 O.J. (L 43) 25. On its treatment of the money-back guarantee,<br />

see Benjamin Geva, Cross-Border Credit Transfers in Euros: Legal and Operational Aspects, in<br />

YEARBOOK OF INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL AND ECONOMIC LAW 173, 173-98 (Joseph J. Norton ed..<br />

1999).<br />

222. Commission Proposal, supra note 126, art. 71.<br />

223. The provision goes on to require processing to be carried out according to Directive 95/46.<br />

Council Directive 95/46, 1995 O.J. (L 281) 31.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 724 2006-2007


2007 INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LAW OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS 725<br />

E. Final Remarks<br />

Purporting to facilitate the establishment of a Single Payment Market where<br />

improved economies of scale and competition would help to reduce costs of the<br />

payment system, the Commission proposed to establish a common framework for<br />

the Community payments market, creating the conditions for integration and<br />

rationalisation of national payment systems. Focusing on electronic payments, the<br />

Commission made a proposal for a Directive on payment services in the internal<br />

market, designed to provide for a harmonised legal framework. Intended to leave<br />

maximum room for self-regulation of industry, the Proposed Directive purports to<br />

harmonise only what is necessary to overcome legal barriers to a Single Euro<br />

Payment Area (SEPA).<br />

However, in the final analysis, steps taken towards Pan-European common<br />

legal principles are quite modest. Payment amount ceilings and a narrow range of<br />

selected topics, primarily focusing on the payer-bank and payee-bank relationships,<br />

resulted in a scheme whose scope and contents cannot be compared for example to<br />

of UCC Article 4A. Arguably, too much room was left for national general laws to<br />

fill in blanks. Nevertheless, the proposal goes beyond consumer aspects. As for<br />

payment transactions covered, besides credit transfers, the proposal covers debit<br />

transfers. Its solutions are reasonable in meeting the needs of the various<br />

participants. Hence, the proposal is a noteworthy milestone in the march to a<br />

comprehensive payment law. There is however still a long way to go to such a final<br />

destination. It remains to be seen how much will and determination exist to go<br />

further, and if so, how far.<br />

VI. CONCLUSION<br />

The four topics covered in this survey are the transformation of the check<br />

payment into an electronic funds transfer, the payroll card as an access and not<br />

stored-value device, the emergence of indirect holding for securities and the ensuing<br />

evolution of "security entitlement" as a principal form of investment property, and<br />

the march towards a Pan-European common payment law covering electronic retail<br />

funds transfers. A common theme is the adaptation of the law by statute to<br />

accommodate the world of electronic banking as it keeps evolving.<br />

Regarding the electronic presentment of checks, Canada did not proceed to<br />

adopt the proposal of the Canadian Payments Association discussed in Part II.D.<br />

Rather, it amended the Bills of Exchange Act 24 to permit... a bank to present for<br />

payment an "official image" of an "eligible bill", 26 including a check, "electronically<br />

in accordance with by-laws, rules or standards made under the Canadian Payments<br />

224. Section 398 of An Act to amend the law governing financial institutions and to provide for<br />

related and consequential matters S.C. 2007, c. 6, which received Royal assent on March 29, 2007. Section<br />

398 came into force April 20, 2007. It adds Sections 163.1-163.6 to the Bills of Exchange Act, note 41,<br />

supra. Unless indicated otherwise, statutory references in this Addendum are to the Bills of Exchange Act<br />

as amended.<br />

225. New Section 163.3.<br />

226. Defined in New Section 163.1 as: "a bill that is of a class specified by a by-law, a rule or a<br />

standard made under the Canadian Payments Act."<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 725 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:685<br />

Act" in which case the requirements of the Bills of Exchange Act respecting the<br />

presentment for payment of the check "are deemed to have been complied with."<br />

An "official image" is defined in New Section 163.1 as:<br />

"an image of [an] eligible bill created by or on behalf of a bank in<br />

accordance with bylaws, rules or standards made under the Canadian<br />

Payments Act, together with any data in relation to the eligible bill<br />

prepared in accordance with those. by-laws, rules and standards, and<br />

includes a display, a printout, a copy or any other output of that image and<br />

that data created by or on behalf of a bank in accordance with those bylaws,<br />

rules and standards. "<br />

An official image of a check "may be dealt with and used for all purposes as<br />

though it were the [check]"; 27 together with the check it is discharged "if payment in<br />

due course is made by or on behalf of the drawee after the electronic presentment<br />

for payment of the official image.. . '' 22 . An official image further benefits from<br />

presumptions of authenticity 229 and of being a true and complete copy of the original<br />

check; 23° it is also admissible in evidence. 2 1 ' A properly destroyed check, for which<br />

there is an official image, is not considered lost, materially altered or intentionally<br />

cancelled; its lawful destruction does not affect the rights, powers, duties and<br />

liabilities of any person, by virtue of lack of possession or otherwise. 32<br />

Finally, a bank that creates an official image warrants its authenticity, accuracy,<br />

and compliance with all requirements and is liable for damages suffered by any<br />

person as a result of the breach of this warranty. 233<br />

The new provisions do not cover electronic presentment made outside the<br />

check clearing system operated by the Canadian Payments Association.<br />

227. New Section 163.2.<br />

228. New Section 163.3(2).<br />

229. New Sections 163.4(1)<br />

230. New Section 163.4(3).<br />

231. New Section 163.4(2)<br />

232. New Section 163.5.<br />

233. New Section 163.6.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 726 2006-2007


Secured Lending and Its Poverty Reduction<br />

Effect<br />

BORIS KOZOLCHYK*<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF COMMERCIAL SECURED LENDING ................. 728<br />

II. POVERTY, MICRO, CONSUMER AND COMMERCIAL CREDIT ......................... 729<br />

A. Micro-Credit and Its Non-Title Collateral ................................................ 730<br />

B. Commercial Lending and the Self-Liquidating Loan .............................. 732<br />

1. Key Features of Commercial Collateral and the Immateriality of<br />

Its T itle ................................................................................................... 7 3 2<br />

C. Commercial Lending and Debtor and Creditor Protection .................... 736<br />

III. CULTURAL AND LEGAL FACTORS .................................................................... 737<br />

A. The Relative Importance of Legal Title ..................................................... 737<br />

B. Duties Toward Family, Friends, and Strangers ........................................ 739<br />

C. The Legal Protection of Strangers or Third Parties and the Credit<br />

M arketp lace ................................................................................................. 741<br />

1. The Wrong Choice of Protected Third Parties ................................. 741<br />

2. The W rong Choice of Protection ........................................................ 742<br />

3. Factors in the Choice of the Right Third Parties and Their<br />

P rotection .............................................................................................. 743<br />

IV.<br />

LEGAL FACTS OF SECURED LENDING AND THEIR GUIDING PRINCIPLES....744<br />

A. The Universality of Effective Secured Lending Practice and Its<br />

P rin cip les ...................................................................................................... 744<br />

B. The N L CIFT Principles .............................................................................. 745<br />

President and Director, National <strong>Law</strong> Center for Inter-American Free Trade (NLCIFT), Evo<br />

DeConcini Professor of <strong>Law</strong>, James E. Rogers College of <strong>Law</strong>, University of Arizona. This Articleoriginally<br />

intended for presentation to the International Academy of Commercial and Consumer <strong>Law</strong><br />

August 2006 meeting in Austin, Texas-was enlarged to incorporate portions of the Author's keynote<br />

address to the November 16, 2006 Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta (Miami, Florida) forum, "Latin<br />

America Looks East - Issues, Trends, and Progress in the Global Economy." The Author gratefully<br />

acknowledges research materials provided by Wade Channell, Esq. (Senior Legal Advisor to USAID), and<br />

the editorial and research assistance of his NLCIFT colleagues, Kevin O'Shea, J.D.; Dr. Mariana Silveira;<br />

Mina Goldberg; Marek Dubovec, L.L.M.; and Lic. Joaquin Picado, L.L.M. candidate, Professor of <strong>Law</strong> at<br />

the University of Costa Rica <strong>Law</strong> School and Member of the Costa Rican Bar Association.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 727 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:727<br />

V. CONCLUSIONS AND A CORRECTIVE STRATEGY .............................................. 748<br />

I. THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF COMMERCIAL SECURED LENDING<br />

Commercial loans (also known as secured loans or as secured transactions) are<br />

loans particularly suited to satisfy the credit needs of small- and medium-sized<br />

enterprises. While their key features will be described in detail in the following<br />

sections, their economic significance must be appreciated from the outset. Because<br />

secured lending reduces commercial risks, it increases the borrowers' access to credit<br />

and lowers the rates of interest. The role that the risk of non-payment plays as a<br />

component of the rates of interest is apparent in a 1999-2000 study by the Central<br />

Bank of Brazil: 1 One-third of the approximately forty percent per annum interest<br />

rate paid at that time by Brazilian commercial borrowers was attributable to the<br />

legal uncertainties of collection. 2<br />

On the other hand, World Bank studies demonstrate that in a competitive<br />

lending environment, the risk reduction that results from adopting an effective<br />

secured lending system can be passed on as savings to the borrower in the form of<br />

lower interest rates. For example, in Albania, adoption of a modern secured lending<br />

system in 2001 reduced risk premiums by half and lowered interest rates by five<br />

percentage points, while in Romania, the rate of interest dropped by twenty percent<br />

since the new system was introduced in 2000.' Similarly, Mexico's 2003 amendments<br />

to its secured transactions law, which reduced some of the risks of collection, helped<br />

its economy grow "at a 4% rate during 2004 and ... all credit sectors are growing at<br />

an annual rate exceeding 20%."' Speaking to a bankers' meeting in 2005, Alfonso<br />

Garcfa Tames, then Mexico's Deputy Secretary of the Treasury, noted that:<br />

Commercial credit showed a favorable rate of growth during the last<br />

three trimesters of 2004. In fact, between 2003 and 2004, the increase in<br />

1. Departamento De Estudios E Pesquisa, Banco Central Do Brasil, Juros e Spread Bancdrio no<br />

Brasil (1999-2000) [hereinafter Central Bank of Brazil Study].<br />

2. Id.<br />

3. See generally Mehnaz Safavian, Heywood Fleisig & Jevgenijs Steinbuks, Unlocking Dead Capital:<br />

How Reforming Collateral <strong>Law</strong>s Improves Access to Finance, 307 WORLD BANK PUB. POL'Y J., Mar. 2006,<br />

available at http://rru.worldbank.org/documents/publicpolicyjournal/307Safavian-Fleisig-Steinbuks.pdf; see<br />

also Wade Channell, Presentation at the Annual Conference of the Economic Freedom of the World<br />

Network, Nov. 2-5, 2006, Costa Rica, Freedom to Pledge: Expanding the Realm of Property Rights for<br />

Increased Access to Credit (Nov. 3, 2006), available at http://www.inlap.org/efn/Papers/Wade%20Channell--<br />

paper.htm.<br />

4. Bancos prevgn expansi6n sostenida del crdito en Mxico, REUTERS, Mar. 3, 2005. The article<br />

states:<br />

ACAPULCO, M6xico (Reuters) - El cr6dito bancario volverfa a crecer cerca de 25 por ciento<br />

en el 2005 en M6xico, por encima de las expectativas iniciales de la banca y apoyado en la<br />

expansi6n de la economia local, estim6 el jueves Manuel Medina Mora, presidente de la<br />

Asociaci6n de Bancos de M6xico (ABM). La economia mexicana creci6 4.4 por ciento en el<br />

2004 .... "Se sigue acelerando el crecimiento del cr6dito y creemos que dada la expansi6n<br />

econ6mica de nuestro pais, podemos esperar crecimientos importantes," dijo Medina Mora en<br />

rueda de prensa, durante la 68 Convenci6n Bancaria en el balneario de Acapulco, que organiza<br />

la ABM. "Por primera vez en una d6cada crecen todos los circuitos de cr6dito y todos por<br />

encima del 20 por ciento .... Cada mes, el crecimiento porcentual es mayor," ahiadi6.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 728 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURED LENDING AND ITS POVERTY REDUCTION EFFECT<br />

this portfolio was 16.8% in real terms. In turn, the credit to consumers<br />

also showed great dynamism, with annual rates of growth of 38.6% in the<br />

last four years. In the last trimester of 2004, the percentage of real<br />

growth was 41 percent in relation to the growth during the same<br />

trimester in the preceding year.<br />

These findings were consistent with the studies by another World Bank economist<br />

who estimated that the absence of commercial credit amounts to a loss of three to<br />

nine percent of a Latin American country's GDP. 6<br />

The effects of a sound secured lending law are felt also in other economic<br />

sectors beyond those traditionally associated with small- and medium-sized<br />

commerce, such as in the securitization of the revenues derived from constructionand<br />

especially housing projects. This type of financing is made possible by the sale in<br />

secondary markets of low- and middle-income housing mortgages and deeds of trust.<br />

Hence, it contributes hundreds of billions of dollars of construction financing<br />

annually to the economies of the United <strong>State</strong>s and other developed nations,<br />

especially in Europe. Directly or indirectly, securitization relies on the personal<br />

property security afforded by the possession of documents that incorporate<br />

creditors' (security holders') rights in the underlying properties.<br />

II.<br />

POVERTY, MICRO, CONSUMER AND COMMERCIAL CREDIT<br />

From an economic development standpoint, poverty has been defined as a<br />

"lack of access to essential goods, services, assets and opportunities to which every<br />

human being is entitled." 7 Having lived among many who have experienced it<br />

firsthand, I would add despair and distrust for social institutions as predominant<br />

feelings among the poor. Unfortunately, those who experience such feelings have<br />

little impetus for self-improvement. What is even more unfortunate is that despair<br />

5. Alonso Garcia Tames, Mexico Deputy Secretary of the Treasury, Versi6n Estenogrifica de la<br />

Mensaje del Act. Alonso Garcia Tamds, Subsecretario de Hacienda y Cr6dito Ptiblico, Durante la<br />

Ceremonia de Clausura de la 68 Convenci6n Bancaria, Efectuada en el Sal6n de Sesiones del Hotel<br />

Acapulco Princess (Mar. 4, 2005) (transcript available at<br />

http://www.natlaw.com/interam/mx/bk/sp/spmxbkl2.pdf). The article states:<br />

El crddito comercial vigente mostr6 un crecimiento favorable durante los tOltimos tres<br />

trimestres de 2004. De hecho, entre 2003 y 2004 el incremento de esta cartera fue de 16.8 por<br />

ciento en t6rminos reales. Por su parte, el crddito al consumo ha presentado un gran<br />

dinamismo, con crecimientos anuales en promedio del 38.6 por ciento en los tjltimos cuatro<br />

afios. En el tercer trimestre de 2004, el crecimiento de esta cartera fue de 41 por ciento en<br />

t6rminos reales con relaci6n al mismo trimestre del afio anterior. Por otra parte, el cr~dito<br />

hipotecario present6 al cierre de 2004 un crecimiento anual real de 4.8 y 24.5 por ciento sin<br />

considerar la cartera asociada a programas de reestructura.<br />

Id. at4.<br />

6. See Heywood W. Fleisig, Assessing the Economic Cost of Deficiencies in the Framework for Secured<br />

Transactions: Examinations of Argentina and Bolivia (Center for Economic Analysis of <strong>Law</strong>, Working<br />

Paper, 1996) [hereinafter Fleisig, Assessing the Economic Cost of Deficiencies], available at<br />

http://www.ceal.org/ceal-org/working.asp; Heywood Fleisig, Secured Transactions: The Power of Collateral,<br />

FIN. & DEV., June 1996, at 44, available at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/1996/06/pdf/fleisig.pdf.<br />

7. Asian Development Bank, Enhancing the Fight Against Poverty in Asia and the Pacific: The<br />

Poverty Reduction Strategy of the Asian Development Bank 1 (2004), available at<br />

http://www.adb.org/Documents/Policies[Poverty-Reduction/2004/prs-2004.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 729 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:727<br />

and distrust need not prevail. Even if poverty may never be completely eradicated,<br />

it can be significantly alleviated by legal institutions that make it possible for micro-,<br />

small-, and medium-sized businesses to obtain commercial and consumer credit at<br />

reasonable rates of interest.<br />

A cursory review of recent literature of economic development reveals hopeful<br />

signs. For example, a December 2004 study by the Asian Development Bank<br />

(ADB) identified rapid, broad-based economic growth as the single most important<br />

factor in attaining poverty reduction. 8 It showed that business growth, in particular,<br />

increases the demand for labour and the level of wages-further reducing poverty.<br />

Similarly, properly financed opportunities for self-employment have been proven to<br />

make an important contribution to poverty reduction. 9<br />

The above study is one among many serious economic and social science<br />

analyses conducted by various research institutions in the last two decades. They<br />

have confirmed that access to commercial and consumer credit is one of the essential<br />

elements of business and economic growth. Thus, it is becoming increasingly clear to<br />

economists and social scientists that the availability of commercial credit to smalland<br />

medium-sized merchants and their customers not only boosts overall economic<br />

growth (as reflected in significant gains in GDP), but it also reduces poverty. '°<br />

Accordingly, a 2004 World Bank study, using a broad cross-country sample,<br />

concluded that: "Financial intermediary development reduces income inequality by<br />

disproportionately boosting the income of the poor and therefore reduces poverty.""<br />

A. Micro-Credit and Its Non-Title Collateral<br />

Some of this intermediation is attributable to "micro-credit," a credit that<br />

enables individuals in the lowest income sectors of the economy to run very small<br />

businesses-micro-enterprises-that, in turn, increase household income and assets.<br />

Thus, micro-enterprise programs become effective fighters of poverty, and one of<br />

these programs has recently been rewarded with a Nobel Prize for its success in<br />

stemming despair and starvation in Bangladesh 2 In a nutshell, these programs<br />

8. Id. at 6.<br />

9. See id.<br />

10. Fleisig, Assessing the Economic Cost of Deficiencies, supra note 6 (estimating the GDP<br />

improvement up to nine percent).<br />

11. See Thorsten Beck, Asti Demirgtiq-Kunt & Ross Levine, Finance, Inequality and Poverty: Cross-<br />

Country Evidence (World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3338, June 2004), available at<br />

http://www.econ.worldbank.org (follow "Research Website" hyperlink; follow "Working Papers"<br />

hyperlink; and then search by paper no.). According to these authors, "a broad sample of 52 developing<br />

and developed countries, with data averaged over the period 1960 to 1999" establishes a direct relationship<br />

between "financial intermediary development and changes in income distribution." Id. at 3. They add<br />

that:<br />

This relationship is crucial in understanding the linkage between financial development and<br />

poverty alleviation since poverty reduction in any given country is determined by the growth of<br />

mean income and changes in income distribution. Given that there is already significant<br />

evidence that financial development is pro-growth, we seek to determine whether financial<br />

development is also pro-poor. By pro-poor, we mean does financial development significantly<br />

improve income distribution by disproportionately boosting the incomes of the poor?<br />

Id.<br />

12. See U.S. Agency for International Development (USAID), Accelerated Microenterprise<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 730 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURED LENDING AND ITS POVERTY REDUCTION EFFECT<br />

make "'cashew shellers in Senegal, avocado growers in Kenya, makers of hand-made<br />

paper in Bangladesh, and street vendors in Mexico less vulnerable to devastating<br />

crises.<br />

'<br />

Micro-credit does not rely on the borrower's title to his or (more frequently)<br />

her assets as collateral or as a source of repayment to the lender. It relies on the<br />

borrower's appreciation of the importance of the loan and corresponding willingness<br />

to repay it. Appreciation and willingness are such that many borrowers are often<br />

willing to cover for each other's liabilities. 4 Yet, micro-entrepreneurs operating in<br />

the large informal economy-including many businesses owned by women-lack<br />

adequate financing to grow once their enterprise can start employing more than a<br />

handful employees. As a result, micro-enterprises "have less of an impact on<br />

economic growth than they might otherwise have."'"<br />

Significantly, where commercial credit is available to small- and medium-sized<br />

enterprises, micro-enterprises can also become its beneficiaries and poverty is<br />

thereby further alleviated. As shown by the above-referenced World Bank Study,<br />

"the income of the poorest quintile grows faster than average GDP per capita in<br />

countries with better-developed financial intermediaries" (i.e., commercial or<br />

"mainstream" lenders). 6 What is more, "income inequality ... falls more rapidly in<br />

countries with higher levels of financial intermediary" lending." Not surprisingly,<br />

then, countries with developed financial intermediaries experience larger reductions<br />

in infant mortality and lesser reliance on child labor. 8 Hence, as concluded by<br />

another World Bank economist, microfinance and finance of small- and mediumsized<br />

businesses are complementary, rather than competing, alternatives, especially<br />

when addressing the problem of poverty." 9<br />

Advancement Project (AMAP), Poverty Assessment Tools, http://www.povertytools.org (last visited Apr.<br />

18, 2007); see also Grameen Website, www.grameen-info.org (last visited Apr. 18, 2007) (on the work of<br />

the 2006 Bangladeshi Nobel Prize-winning economics professor and banker Mohammed Yunnus who won<br />

the Nobel Peace Prize and whose methods have been used in fifty-eight countries).<br />

13. IRIS Center, IRIS Helps Ensure that Microenterprise Funds Reach the Very Poor (2005) (quoting<br />

Dr. Thierry van Bastelaer, Director, IRIS Center's Enterprise Development Group), available at<br />

http://www.iris.umd.edu/Reader.aspx?TYPE-HTMLARTICLE&ID=b7fd59e-9651-4696-accb-<br />

070fa88969f8.<br />

14. See Rania El Gamal, Microfinance: Fighting World's Poverty Through Investment, KUWAIT<br />

TIMES, June 12, 2006, available at http://www.businessdayonline.com/?c=44&a=7017.<br />

15. Removing Obstacles for African Entrepreneurs Before the Subcommittee on Africa, Global Human<br />

Rights and International Operations of the Committee on International Relations, 109th Cong. 3 (2006)<br />

(prepared statement of Christopher H. Smith, Chairman, House Subcommittee on Africa, Global Human<br />

Rights and International Operations), available at<br />

http://www.internationalrelations.house.gov/archives/109/27989.pdf.<br />

16. Beck, Demirgiiq-Kunt & Levine, supra note 11, at 4.<br />

17. Id.<br />

18. Id. at 12 (concerning infant mortality); id. at 4 (concerning child labor, which refers to the World<br />

Bank's recent work that analyzes the link between financial development and child labor).<br />

In a cross-country sample, Dehejia and Gatti (2002) find that the incidence of child labor is<br />

lower in countries with greater financial depth and that financial deepening dampens the<br />

impact of income volatility on child labor. Similarly, using a panel dataset of Tanzanian<br />

households, Beegle, Dehejia and Gatti (2003) find that child labor is used to buffer transitory<br />

income shocks less when households have access to credit.<br />

Id. at 5.<br />

19. Patrick Honohan, Financial Sector Policy and the Poor: Selected Findings and Issues 30-33, 43-44<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 731 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:727<br />

B. Commercial Lending and the Self-Liquidating Loan<br />

Unlike micro-credit, commercial lending enables the "mobilization" of the<br />

debtor's assets as collateral and thereby facilitates repayment. This method of<br />

lending-institutionalized in eighteenth century England" 0 and fully developed in the<br />

twentieth century United <strong>State</strong>s-stands in sharp contrast to the lending methods<br />

that prevail in most developing nations. 2 ' In these nations, the debtors' assets are<br />

pledged and immobilized either by the creditors' possession or by their "safe"<br />

storage with third parties. Once immobilized, the release of these assets for resale,<br />

re-pledge, or transformation is only possible upon full repayment of the debt. In<br />

contrast, the Anglo-American commercial lending practice relies upon the<br />

mobilization of the assets by allowing the debtor to remain in possession of these<br />

assets and authorizing their use, transformation, exchange, or sale, thereby enabling<br />

the "self-liquidation" of the loan. As stated by the NLCIFT's First Principle of<br />

Secured Transactions <strong>Law</strong> in the Americas, and as implicit in the OAS Model <strong>Law</strong><br />

and the Latin American statutes and legislative drafts inspired by these principles:<br />

Secured commercial and consumer credit is an effective tool for economic<br />

development because it allows the debtor's use, transformation, sale or<br />

barter of collateral (mobilization). The mobilization of these assets<br />

leading to their sale or disposition makes possible the payment or selfliquidation<br />

of the loan ... 22<br />

1. Key Features of Commercial Collateral and the Immateriality of Its Title<br />

Because of the self-liquidating nature of the commercial loan, its collateral has<br />

peculiar features. Firstly-and in contrast with the collateral in a home mortgage,<br />

(World Bank, Working Paper No. 43, 2004), available at<br />

http://wwwl.worldbank.org/finance/assets/images/0821359673-Financial-Sector-Policy-and-the Poor.pdf#<br />

search=%22%22Financial%20Sector%20Policy%20and%20the%2OPoor%22%22.<br />

20. The view of commercial loans (extended to "able" men) as self-liquidating, and of retail trade and<br />

consumption loans as dependent upon the honesty of "good" men, which became part of the Bank of England's<br />

credit policies, was articulated in the following excerpt:<br />

There are Two sorts of Credit; the one, is Grounded upon the Ability of the Buyer the other,<br />

upon the Honesty: The first is called a Good Man, which implys an Able Man he generally<br />

buys upon short Time; to pay in a Month, which is accounted as ready Mony, and the Price is<br />

made accordingly. The other is accounted an Honest Man; He may be poor; he Generally buys<br />

for three and Six Months or longer, so as to pay the Merchant by the Return of his own Goods;<br />

and therefore, the Seller relys more upon the Honesty of the Buyer, than his Ability: Most of<br />

the Retail Traders buy upon this Sort of Credit, and are usually Trusted for more than double<br />

they are worth.<br />

NICHOLAS BARBON, A DISCOURSE OF TRADE 19 (Jacob H. Hollander ed., Lord Baltimore Press 1905) (1690).<br />

21. See generally Boris Kozolchyk & Dale B. Furnish, The OAS Model <strong>Law</strong> on Secured Transactions:<br />

A Comparative Analysis, 12 Sw. J. L. & TRADE AM. 235 (2006). For an analysis of the status of law and<br />

lending practice in Latin America, and for surveys of the law and practice in other regions, see Safavian,<br />

Fleisig & Steinbuks, supra note 3. See also Channell, supra note 3.<br />

22. See National <strong>Law</strong> Center for Inter-American Free Trade, 12 Principles of Secured Transactions<br />

<strong>Law</strong> in the Americas, princs. 1 (2006) [hereinafter NLCIFT Principles], available at<br />

http://www.natlaw.com/bci9.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 732 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURED LENDING AND ITS POVERTY REDUCTION EFFECT<br />

which is immobile, long-lasting, and retains or increases its value during the life of<br />

the loan-the collateral of a commercial loan is mobile, perishable, and usually<br />

depreciates quickly in value. Consequently, and secondly, any moveable (tangible or<br />

intangible) object with sufficient market value to facilitate quick repayment of a<br />

commercial loan by its transformation, exchange, or resale can be collateral.<br />

Contrast this open number (numerus apertus) feature of commercial lending with the<br />

prevailing restrictive or closed number (numerus clausus) approach to collateral that<br />

prevails in developing countries. 23 Thus, as pointed out by Safavian and Fleisig,<br />

Nigeria (among many other developing nations) recognizes only ten percent of the<br />

types of assets used in the United <strong>State</strong>s as acceptable security for a loan. 24<br />

Thirdly, this open-numbered collateral can secure the loan of not one but many<br />

possible creditors simultaneously and successively. Consider, for example, the case<br />

of a retail merchant who seeks credit to purchase inventory goods such as shirts.<br />

These shirts, and the proceeds from their resale to the public, could be the collateral<br />

or part of the collateral that will secure the credit extended to him by a wholesaler or<br />

manufacturer, or by his bank. The proceeds of the sale of the shirts could also be<br />

collateral. These proceeds could be either moneys deposited in the retail merchant's<br />

cash register after each sale, or they could be purchase orders, invoices, checks,<br />

promissory notes, or credit card receipts deposited in his creditors' bank accounts, all<br />

as a result of daily, weekly, or monthly sales. Alternatively, they could be other<br />

inventory or other goods acquired as replacements for the originally-financed shirts.<br />

This revolving (including future-acquired) inventory and proceeds can serve as<br />

collateral for many creditors, with rights in them that can exist at the same time or be<br />

subsequently acquired. This "sharing" of present and future collateral by present<br />

and future creditors is possible because, from a legal standpoint, the ownership of<br />

the collection of goods that comprise the inventory and of their proceeds is<br />

fragmented into diverse possessory rights of specified scope or inclusiveness and<br />

duration. The enforcement of these rights requires that information be provided on<br />

the perfection of the possessory rights and their priorities to creditors or purchasers<br />

who may have an interest in relying on the same assets as collateral or in purchasing<br />

them. For this information to serve as effective and functional notice it must be a<br />

summary of the lien that is reliable, timely, and as public or widely accessible and as<br />

transparent as possible. Commercial and secured lending has no worse enemy than<br />

hidden or secret liens-i.e., rights that are either unrecorded or whose possession for<br />

security purposes is not apparent to a potential creditor or purchaser. Finally,<br />

enforcement of these possessory rights requires a quick, inexpensive, and<br />

extrajudicial procedure of repossession and resale.<br />

Let us now observe the interaction between the fragmentation of ownership of<br />

the collateral and the possessory and malleable nature of the creditors' rights in a<br />

typical U.S. financing scheme. Assume that the goods that will be manufactured will<br />

be the above-mentioned shirts. For ease of explanation (and contrary to what has<br />

become the U.S. commercial practice of outsourcing of most manual labor), let us<br />

23. In the Central American region, see, for example, the C6digo Civil and the C6digo de Comercio.<br />

See, e.g., COD. CIV. [Civil Code] art. 441 (Costa Rica) (the "traditional" or possessory pledge (prenda con<br />

tenencia)); COD. COM. [Commercial Code] art. 442 (Costa Rica) (the "pledge of a credit" (prenda de un<br />

crddito)): id. arts. 530, 533 (the "commercial pledge" (prenda comercial)); id. art. 537 ("pledge with<br />

dispossession" (prenda sin tenencia)); COD.CIv. arts. 880-903 (Guatemala) (the pledge (prenda)).<br />

24. Safavian, Fleisig & Steinbuks, supra note 3.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 733 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:727<br />

assume that the shirts are manufactured in the United <strong>State</strong>s. The manufacturer will<br />

need credit with which to purchase his raw materials and equipment. Accordingly,<br />

he will seek a loan from a bank and will grant this bank as a secured creditor a<br />

security interest. The security interest will typically include not only the raw<br />

materials and equipment but also the present and future inventory of shirts and their<br />

proceeds. Similarly, the wholesaler and retailers who will purchase the manufactured<br />

shirts from the manufacturer will need credit for their respective acquisitions.<br />

In each acquisition, present and future inventories as well as their proceeds will<br />

serve as collateral. Yet, during the time the manufacturer's shirts are being shipped<br />

by the manufacturer to the wholesalers or retailers, the bank that issued a letter of<br />

credit to pay for the shipped shirts on behalf of the wholesaler or retailer will also<br />

acquire a possessory right in these shirts. This security interest will be perfected by<br />

the manufacturer-shipper's endorsement of a negotiable bill of lading, which attests<br />

to shipment of the goods, to the bank that issued or confirmed the letter of credit.<br />

This negotiable bill of lading will be issued to the shipper by the ocean carrier in<br />

charge of transporting the shirts to the wholesale or retailer. In endorsing the<br />

negotiable bill of lading, the manufacturer-shipper is not only creating the bank's<br />

security interest, but is also providing notice of the existence of the security interest<br />

to the world at large. The reason for this notice is that by transmitting possession of<br />

a document that provides an exclusive right to claim the shirts from the carrier to the<br />

person holding the bill of lading, no one else can make such a claim. Hence, the<br />

bank's possession of this bill of lading will entitle it to claim the delivery of the shirts<br />

from the carrier with a higher priority than that enjoyed by most other claimants of<br />

the shirts.<br />

Among the claimants whose possessory rights or security interests are inferior<br />

to those of the bank that issued the letter of credit are: a) the sellers of the raw<br />

materials or equipment to the manufacturer of the shirts who are still owed part or<br />

all of their purchase prices, or the financiers for the manufacturer's acquisition of the<br />

raw materials or equipment who are still owed all or a portion of their loans; b) the<br />

manufacturer who is still owed the purchase price of the shirts by the wholesale<br />

buyer of the shirts; c) the wholesaler who is owed the purchase price of the shirts<br />

sold to the retailer or the wholesaler's bank, who has not been paid the amount lent<br />

to the wholesaler or retail merchant for their respective purchases of shirts; and d)<br />

the retail merchant who has paid part of the purchase price of the shirts to the<br />

manufacturer or wholesaler. These creditors or purchasers could not seek<br />

possession of the shirts or of the proceeds of their sale until the bank in possession of<br />

the bill of lading has been paid what it is owed for its issuance of the letter of credit.<br />

On the other hand, there are two claimants whose possessory right to the shirts<br />

is superior to that of the bank. One of these claimants is the ocean carrier who has<br />

not been paid his freight charges and who is still in possession of the transported<br />

shirts. The other claimant is the consumer-buyer of the shirts who bought them from<br />

the retail or wholesale merchant in the ordinary course of their respective<br />

businesses. Where such a buyer exists, none of the pre-existing unpaid secured<br />

lenders or commercial purchasers can repossess or recover the shirts from him. The<br />

creditors' secured claims could only be made effective against the proceeds obtained<br />

by the retailers, wholesalers, or manufacturers from the sales of the shirts to the<br />

consumers.<br />

The above rights to the possession of the collateral are more malleable (if not<br />

ephemeral) than those of a typical home-mortgagee. Moreover, the only party<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 734 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURED LENDING AND ITS POVERTY REDUCTION EFFECT<br />

whose right to the possession of the shirt approximates the right of ownership of a<br />

home-mortgagor is that of the consumer-buyer in the ordinary course of business.<br />

Yet, unlike the home owner, the possessory right of the consumer is not the product<br />

of a "historical" or linear chain of transactions or being the holder of a Hernando de<br />

Soto's talismanic ownership document. 25 The consumer-purchaser's possessory right<br />

is a product of the lawmakers' decision to protect a third party who is a stranger to<br />

the preceding chain of transactions. Without such a protection (which means<br />

providing the stranger with immunity against pre-existing possessory rights), the<br />

viability of a marketplace whose participants are predominantly strangers would be<br />

undermined as they would fear buying, borrowing, exchanging, or otherwise<br />

participating in the marketplace. 26<br />

What matters in the law of commercial lending, then, is not who is the<br />

"historical" owner of the shirts or who is the creditor with the best chain of title to<br />

the shirts, but who has the best right to their possession or to their market value at a<br />

given point during the transactional and useful life of the shirts or of their proceeds.<br />

Accordingly, the "being" of rights in a collateral such as the original inventory shirts,<br />

which can become cash or commercial paper and reappear as tangible goods (such as<br />

new shirts or other inventory) or be transformed into intangible goods (such as<br />

accounts or wire transfers), resembles that of the river described by the Greek<br />

philosopher Heraclites as: "You cannot step twice into the same river, for other<br />

waters and yet others go ever flowing on." 27 Accordingly, when a merchant pledges<br />

his inventory, title to this collateral is, in the words of the Uniform Commercial<br />

Code, "immaterial." 28 In the final analysis, then, the meaning of collateral in<br />

commercial lending is not a "thing" or group of things but the right to the possession<br />

of what becomes a stream of income generated by the use, transformation, sale, or<br />

exchange of commercial assets. And by assets we mean any object, tangible or<br />

intangible, deemed valuable in the marketplace by those who participate in it.<br />

The economic and legal policies that determine who has the best right to the<br />

possession of that stream of income are, in the final analysis, those that make the<br />

river of commerce flow best by encouraging contributions to its stream. These<br />

contributions could be by sellers of raw materials, financiers of equipment, providers<br />

of services, or providers of financing with which to acquire any or all of the above<br />

25. See Boris Kozolchyk, A Roadmap to Economic Development Through <strong>Law</strong>: Third Parties and<br />

Comparative Legal Culture, 23 ARIZ. J. INT'L & COMP. L. 1 (2006) [hereinafter Kozolchyk, A Roadmap].<br />

26. See Boris Kozolchyk, The Transfer of Personal Property by a Nonowner: Its Future in Light of its<br />

Past, 61 TUL. L. REV. 1453, 1455 (1987).<br />

The need to protect the bona fide purchaser who acquired from an entrusted intermediary is<br />

justified by market economics. Unless buyers are assured that they will not be deprived by an<br />

unknown owner or creditor of what they honestly acquired in the open market, they will be<br />

afraid to buy. On the other hand, unless the entrusting owners' expectations of recovering the<br />

value of entrusted property are protected, they will hesitate to entrust their property. These<br />

economic realities explain the apparent coexistence of the ancient Roman law maxim 'Nemo<br />

dat quod non habet' with the mercantilistic Bourjon principle of [possession is considered<br />

equivalent to a title, as found first among civil codes in] article 2279 of the French Civil Code of<br />

1800.<br />

Id. at 1455, 1455 n.4.<br />

27. See GREEK PHILOSOPHY AND HERACLITUS (William Harris trans., 2005) (360 BC), available at<br />

http://community.middlebury.edu/-harris/PhilosophyfHeraclitus.html.<br />

28. See U.C.C. § 9-202 (2000).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 735 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:727<br />

items of value. The value of their contribution can be determined or ascribed by the<br />

lawmaker or by the parties to the loan on a quantitative or a qualitative basis, or as a<br />

combination thereof. It is now time to discuss the legal components of an effective<br />

system of secured lending.<br />

C. Commercial Lending and Debtor and Creditor Protection<br />

Fairness in the treatment of debtors and creditors is one of the most important<br />

components of an effective law of secured transactions. Poor debtors lack the<br />

bargaining power of most of their creditors and, hence, become vulnerable to<br />

exploitive and abusive lending practices. A lack of protection against these practices<br />

often leads to the debtors' insolvency and to their inability to function as productive<br />

members of society. Where ordinary or bona fide debtors are treated as criminals,<br />

the result is not only inhumane but also counterproductive-the availability of credit<br />

does not improve, and the cost of credit continues to climb. 29 For these reasons,<br />

debtor protection-particularly of those who are most vulnerable-contributes to<br />

the availability of credit for micro-, small-, and medium-sized businesses.<br />

On the other hand, since credit is only extended when lenders are willing to<br />

lend, adequate creditor protection is key to the availability of finance for small- and<br />

medium-sized businesses as well as for micro finance. In the words of Chilean<br />

Central Bank economic researchers who studied the effect of inadequate monitoring<br />

of bank loans on poorer debtors: "[Ilnefficient [creditor] legal protections,<br />

disproportionately increase financial restrictions for creditors that have less<br />

wealth." 3 The main reason for this restriction is the fixed cost of monitoring debtor<br />

performance by the lending banks. Because these costs are fixed and larger loans<br />

are more profitable, lending banks do not monitor the performance of smaller<br />

borrowers as carefully as they do that of their larger borrowers. Inadequate<br />

monitoring of small borrowers makes it easier for these borrowers to adopt riskier<br />

business and repayment practices. These practices, in turn, lead to a higher<br />

probability of insolvency.<br />

Likewise, inefficiencies in bankruptcy procedures have a greater effect on<br />

small businesses than on large ones. Using a survey of practices in sixty-two<br />

countries, the same Chilean researchers explored the impact of creditor protection<br />

on the availability of bank credit to small- and medium-sized enterprises. They<br />

found that better protection of all creditors reduced the financing gap between<br />

29. See Ley de Jurisdicci6n Constitucional No. 7135, La Gaceta No. 198, art. 113 (1989) (amended in<br />

La Gaceta No. 212 on Nov. 9, 1989), available at http://www.asamblea.go.cr/ley/leyes/7000/7135.doc (stating<br />

the reasons in favor of the abolition of Costa Rica's Civil Code's apremio corporal).<br />

30. Arturo Galindo & Alejandro Micco, Bank Credit to Small and Medium Sized Enterprises: The<br />

Role of Creditor Protection 1 (Banco Central de Chile, Working Paper No. 347, 2005), available at<br />

http://www.bcentral.cl/eng/stdpub/studies/workingpaperhtm/347.htm. Galindo and Micco add:<br />

Id. at 15.<br />

The degree to which smaller firms are constrained depends on the quality of the regulatory<br />

framework, suggesting that in countries where creditor rights are protected (and enforced),<br />

smaller firms have greater access to bank credit to finance investment. In our sample this effect<br />

is large. In common law countries (where creditor protection is high), the difference in the<br />

share of investment financed with bank credit between large and small firms is approximately 9<br />

percentage points. In non-common law countries this difference is 25 percentage points.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 736 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURED LENDING AND ITS POVERTY REDUCTION EFFECT<br />

small and large firms. 31 In light of the above findings, we need to examine the role of<br />

legal and cultural factors in making commercial and consumer credit available at<br />

reasonable rates of interest in developing nations.<br />

III. CULTURAL AND LEGAL FACTORS<br />

A. The Relative Importance of Legal Title<br />

The importance of culture in bringing about economic development has been<br />

questioned-if not discarded-in the influential writings of the Peruvian economist<br />

Hernando de Soto. 32 He points to the negative effect of legal uncertainty, especially<br />

with respect to land titles and other "property document[s]." 33 In his opinion, "the<br />

suggestion that it is culture that explains the success of such diverse places as Japan,<br />

Switzerland and California and culture again that explains the relative poverty of<br />

such equally diverse places as China, Estonia, and Baja California, is worse than<br />

inhumane; it is unconvincing." 3<br />

De Soto focuses instead on "representational systems," meaning the things or<br />

languages that embody legal certainty for the holder of rights, either to property or<br />

contractual rights, as contrasted with the culture that creates such things or<br />

languages. In de Soto's words:<br />

In the West, by contrast, every parcel of land, every building, every piece<br />

of equipment, or store of inventories is represented in a property<br />

document that is the visible sign of a vast hidden process that connects all<br />

these assets to the rest of the economy. . . . The single most important<br />

source of funds for new businesses in the United <strong>State</strong>s is a mortgage on<br />

the entrepreneur's house."<br />

The preceding examination of the meaning of collateral in micro and<br />

commercial lending showed that title was immaterial for both loans. In the case of<br />

micro lending the likelihood of repayment was caused mostly by the debtors'<br />

appreciation of what he received and his strong desire to continue to receive this<br />

credit. With commercial lending, the above-quoted statement and especially "every<br />

piece of equipment, or store of inventories is represented in a property document" is<br />

equally untrue. 36 Furthermore, what prompts the lender's willingness to loan is not<br />

the borrower's title to the collateral, but the self-liquidating nature of the collateral<br />

and his right to its possession as protected by a system of public notice-regardless<br />

of who is or was the historical owner of the collateral. Even with respect to lending<br />

secured by land or real estate in Latin America and elsewhere, the role of title is not<br />

31. Id. at 2.<br />

32. See generally HERNANDO DE SOTO, THE MYSTERY OF CAPITAL: WHY CAPITALISM TRIUMPHS IN<br />

THE WEST AND FAILS EVERYWHERE ELSE (2000); Kozolchyk, A Roadmap, supra note 25 (discussing<br />

some of Hernando de Soto's writings).<br />

33. DE SOTO, supra note 32, at 6.<br />

34. Id. at 4.<br />

35. Id.<br />

36. DE SOTOsupra note 32, at 6.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 737 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:727<br />

as necessary and sufficient as may be inferred from de Soto's writings. As concluded<br />

by Erica Field and Maximo Torero in their Harvard University study:<br />

Detailed data collected on loans from different financial institutions also<br />

enables us to compare the impact of title acquisition among banks with<br />

alternative lending strategies. We find that land titling [in Peru's land<br />

titling program inspired by Hernando de Soto's studies] is associated with<br />

a 9-10 percentage point increase in loan approval rates from the public<br />

sector bank for housing construction materials, while there appears to be<br />

37<br />

no effect on the loan approval rate of private sector lenders ....<br />

Similar studies were conducted in Argentina by Professors Sebastian Galiani<br />

and Ernesto Schardgrodsky. 8 These scholars found that while secure land rights<br />

encourage the poor to build their homes,<br />

even in a relatively advanced country such as Argentina, title is not<br />

enough in itself to animate the dead capital interred in land and property..<br />

. T]he titled households enjoyed no better access to bank loans, credit<br />

cards or bank accounts, and only 4% of them managed to acquire a<br />

mortgage . 39<br />

Finally, an April 2006 study, The Effects on Property Titling in Langa Township<br />

South Africa, conducted by Karol Boudreaux of George Mason University,<br />

confirmed the findings of the studies conducted in Peru and Argentina, where<br />

commercial lending was concerned:<br />

Today, most homes-though not shacks-have titles. . . . Has this<br />

government policy led to economic growth and poverty alleviation for<br />

Langa's residents? The answer is a qualified yes. By creating secure<br />

property rights in houses, the South African government has created<br />

incentives for owners to improve their homes and to use them for homebased<br />

businesses, thus creating jobs and income in poor communities.<br />

However, more needs to be done. Few Langa residents use their titles as<br />

collateral for commercial loans, still preferring to rely on personal savings<br />

and savings clubs. Titling is not enough. Institutional weaknesses make<br />

the use of title as collateral too risky for many Langa residents . . . and<br />

regulatory burdens make it costly to grow and expand small businesses. ' °<br />

Even if graphic representations of the rights of ownership to land carried with<br />

them talismanic effects causing credit and investment certainty to prevail, such<br />

effects were inseparable from the culture that attributed certainty to the<br />

37. ERICA FIELD & MAXIMO TORERO, Do PROPERTY TITLES INCREASE CREDIT ACCESS AMONG<br />

THE URBAN POOR? EVIDENCE FROM A NATIONWIDE TITLING PROGRAM 1 (2003) (emphasis added),<br />

available at http://econ.ucsd.edu/seminars/sevenssrc/FieldTorero9l4.pdf.<br />

38. The Mystery of Capital Deepens, THE ECONOMIST, Aug. 26, 2006, at 62, available at<br />

http://defeatpoverty.com/articles/Economist%20Mystery%2ODeepens.pdf.<br />

39. Id.<br />

40. KAROL BOUDREAUX, THE EFFECTS OF PROPERTY TITLING IN LANGA TOWNSHIP, SOUTH<br />

AFRICA (Mercatus Policy Series Policy Comment No. 4, 2006) (emphasis added) (stated in the executive<br />

summary).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 738 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURED LENDING AND ITS POVERTY REDUCTION EFFECT<br />

representation in question. Consequently, cultural-legal factors must be taken into<br />

account. Considering that commercial credit takes place mostly among strangers, it<br />

is especially important to focus on the cultural values that shape the debtors' duties<br />

toward creditors who are neither the debtors' family nor friends.<br />

B. Duties Toward Family, Friends, and Strangers<br />

The 1999 study of the Central Bank of Brazil estimated that one-third of the<br />

approximately forty percent per annum interest rate paid by Brazilian commercial<br />

borrowers was attributable to the difficulties and risks of loan collection and nonrepayment.<br />

1 This is neither an unusual finding nor a recent phenomenon, either in<br />

Brazil or in other Latin American countries. For example, my 1967 RAND<br />

Corporation study <strong>Law</strong> and the Credit Structure in Latin America showed that the<br />

percentages of discounted bills of exchange or drafts protested for lack of payment<br />

in Chile from 1958 to 1962 were, respectively, 31.5%, 26%, 34.4%, 37%, and<br />

39.1%.4' This meant that out of, say, one hundred negotiable and credit instruments<br />

in circulation in Chile in 1962, almost forty had not been paid at maturity. While<br />

during the same period, the protests of negotiable instruments by Argentine banks<br />

fluctuated between one-third and one-half of the Chilean figures, the percentages of<br />

the aggregate uncollected secured and unsecured loans and discounted negotiable<br />

instruments in Argentina (gathered under the rubric of "quasi money") were,<br />

respectively, 2.5%, 2.7%, 6%, 9.5%, and 22.9%. 3 In other words, of the total<br />

number of bank loans, direct or indirect extensions of credit, and negotiable<br />

instruments, as many as twenty-two percent during a peak year were in default.<br />

Neither creditors nor debtors are well-served by a legal culture that makes<br />

collection so difficult and risky for creditors and so expensive for debtors. In<br />

fairness, however, the fault does not lie entirely with the legal culture. Underlying<br />

the legal culture, there is a business culture of "winner take all, loser take none" and<br />

a commerce practiced as a "tricky" or "picaresque" occupation. 4 Such an attitude<br />

toward business has much to do with the cost of credit. The tricky or picaresque<br />

aspects of dealing with checks, drafts, and promissory notes as credit instruments<br />

were reflected in responses given to this writer by Argentine bankers and merchants<br />

as part of the same study.<br />

My first question was: "Why, if protests of negotiable instruments are so<br />

common and their collection so difficult, are you still willing to take checks, drafts, or<br />

notes in payment of what is owed to you?" In response, several of my businessmenrespondents<br />

referred to what they described as the "false-money psychology." This<br />

"psychology" encouraged taking these instruments in payment with the<br />

understanding that as with other "false" money, they would be passed on to<br />

someone else in payment of what the taker owed to them. The next, inevitable<br />

41. See Central Bank of Brazil Study, supra note 1.<br />

42. BORIs KOZOLCHYK, LAW AND THE CREDIT STRUCTURE IN LATIN AMERICA (RAND<br />

Memorandum 4918, 1966). For a somewhat shortened version of the RAND study, see Boris Kozolchyk,<br />

<strong>Law</strong> and the Credit Structure in Latin America, 7 VA. J. INT'L L. 1, tbl. 6 (1967) [hereinafter Kozolchyk,<br />

<strong>Law</strong> and the Credit Structure in Latin America] (shortened version).<br />

43. Kozolchyk, <strong>Law</strong> and the Credit Structure in Latin America (shortened version), supra note 42.<br />

44. Kozolchyk, A Roadmap, supra note 25, at 4.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 739 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:727<br />

question was: "Yet, what if that someone else is equally aware of the falseness of the<br />

money, why would he or she take it?" The answer was: "Because the falsity is<br />

factored into the prices everyone charges for their goods or services." In other<br />

words, a merchant would be willing to take a likely "false" check after he had<br />

charged his customer a much higher price than he would for a cash sale. He would<br />

demand a sufficiently large cash down payment to cover a substantial part of his cost;<br />

he would then gamble on the likelihood of collecting the remainder of the check by<br />

negotiating it to someone else, who would, in all likelihood, engage in the same<br />

picaresque calculation. I recall the interest that these answers evoked among my<br />

RAND Corporation economist-colleagues: picaresque or tricky commercial<br />

behavior acquired an unforeseen economic importance as an explanation for the<br />

ever-increasing levels of prices in Argentina's hyperinflation.<br />

The business culture of "winner take all, loser take none" is not peculiar to<br />

Latin America; it is present in those developing nations that continue to be guided<br />

by standards of fairness particular to agricultural survival-tribal societies." In these<br />

societies, only the members of one's tribe, clan, family, or circle of friends are<br />

considered insiders, and are legally entitled to duties of fair dealing by their fellow<br />

insiders. In contrast, those who belong to other tribes, clans, families, or circles of<br />

friends are deemed outsiders ("strangers") and, as such, are not entitled to the duties<br />

of fair dealing owed to insiders. 46<br />

This is not to say that creditors-strangers are totally without protection in<br />

developing nations. They are usually allowed to "purchase" a temporary protected<br />

status by paying a bribe. Yet this status is only temporary because it only applies to<br />

a specific transaction or event. It is also temporary because it lasts until the same or<br />

a better protection is made available to another (often competing) stranger willing to<br />

pay a similar or higher bribe. At this point, the stranger's protection either<br />

disappears or becomes subject to a bidding war.<br />

The effects of a business and legal culture in which only the most minimal<br />

business duties are owed to strangers, and the widespread feeling of distrust it<br />

inspires in market participants, were apparent in the responses provided by middle<br />

class Costa Ricans in a 1968 questionnaire on their investment practices. When<br />

asked why the respondent, as a potential investor, preferred to invest in real estate<br />

mortgages that offered a smaller return on invested capital than that yielded by the<br />

dividends of stock issued year after year by an industrial company, many<br />

respondents provided variants of the same answer: if the industrial company's<br />

dividend return is such a good deal, why would it be offered to me, neither a<br />

member of the family nor a friend of those who run this company?<br />

45. See Kozolchyk, A Roadmap, supra note 25, at 4; Boris Kozolchyk, Fairness in Anglo and Latin<br />

American Commercial Adjudication, 2 B.C. INT'L & COMP. L. REV. 219, 257 (1979).<br />

46. The first time I discussed the findings in my study, Boris Kozolchyk, Toward a Theory on <strong>Law</strong> in<br />

Economic Development: The Costa Rican USAID-ROCAP <strong>Law</strong> Reform Project, 1971 LAW & SOC.<br />

ORDER 681, with the late and lamented father of legal anthropology, E. Adamson Hoebel, he recalled an<br />

incident he witnessed that illustrates the predicament of the stranger in a tribal environment. Hoebel was<br />

watching a ritual snake dance that involved an actual snake in the hands of a Native American ritual<br />

dancer. This took place at a Native American reservation located near a U.S. national park in the western<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s. At one point, the park ranger asked the tribal dancer to stop his dance so that he could<br />

have the visitors move back from one of the nearby cliffs, lest the snake dart out and scare a visitor who<br />

could then easily fall off the cliff. Somewhat annoyed at the interruption, the dancer asked the ranger:<br />

"Why are you so concerned, are these your family, or are they your friends, do you even know these<br />

people?"<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 740 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURED LENDING AND ITS POVERTY REDUCTION EFFECT<br />

C. The Legal Protection of Strangers or Third Parties and the Credit Marketplace<br />

The present-day commercial marketplace is comprised of countless strangers or<br />

contracting parties who are most often unknown to each other, and who also lack<br />

any connection to transactions entered into by their contracting parties with their<br />

contractual predecessors. These strangers could be investors, lenders, borrowers,<br />

sellers, buyers, carriers, shippers, consignees, insurers, insureds, brokers, credit card<br />

issuers or holders, and so on. As different forms of trade and credit emerge, the list<br />

grows almost endlessly.<br />

These contractual strangers would not be willing to provide or acquire goods or<br />

services, lend, borrow, exchange, or pay, unless they were protected from the claims,<br />

defenses, and equities derived from transactions in which they had not participated<br />

in or been given adequate notice. Many of these strangers are referred to by the<br />

applicable law as protected third parties. In our day, the economic importance of<br />

these third parties is such that no viable commercial or financial marketplace can<br />

exist without providing these third parties adequate legal protection.<br />

1. The Wrong Choice of Protected Third Parties<br />

The provision of adequate legal protection to third parties is not as easy as it<br />

appears. The choice of the wrong party for protection purposes as well as the<br />

excessive or deficient protection of those chosen can be quite costly to society and its<br />

economy. First, the law must determine who-among the many competitors for the<br />

status-qualifies as a third party that is entitled to protection. Second, the law must<br />

establish a form of protection that is deemed fair by the participants in the various<br />

transactions. Case statutory law is not explicit as to who qualifies as a third party<br />

entitled to protection; courts or legal commentators must fill this gap.<br />

Unless courts or commentators are familiar with the transaction or legal<br />

institution in question, their choice of a wrong party may carry serious negative<br />

consequences. Consider, for example, a Costa Rican provincial court decision that<br />

assumed that a given holder of a negotiable draft qualified for the status of holder in<br />

due course entitled to sue a party whose name appeared in the drawee-acceptor's<br />

column of the draft. 7 The party whose name appeared on the face of a draft had<br />

never signed or otherwise accepted such a draft. By allowing such a cause of action,<br />

this decision conferred upon the holder of a draft the right to sue practically anyone<br />

47. Case of the Nonsigned Bill of Exchange by the Accepting-Drawee of Cartago, Costa Rica, Oct. 10,<br />

1966, Juzgado Contencioso Administrativo of the City of Cartago (Costa Rica). See Boris Kozolchyk,<br />

Jurisprudencia Mercantil, Separata Revista de Ciencias Jurfdicas, Universidad de Costa Rica. In January<br />

1968, while preparing summaries of all the reported commercial court decisions by Costa Rican courts<br />

from 1900-1966, Lic. Rodrigo Oreamuno of the San Jose Bar (and much later Vice-President of Costa<br />

Rica), at that time one of the Costa Rican researchers, alerted the Author to a decision by a lower court in<br />

the city of Cartago dated October 10. 1966, which had worried commercial lawyers in San Jose. A few days<br />

later the Author visited with the judge and clerk responsible for this decision. The description of facts and<br />

reasoning that appears in the principal text is part of the notes taken by the Author during these<br />

interviews. These notes are available at http://www.natlaw.com/intlcases.htm (an electronic archive of the<br />

National <strong>Law</strong> Center for Inter-American Free Trade, "significant comparative commercial law cases and<br />

comments").<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 741 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:727<br />

whose name appeared in the drawee-acceptor's column, even though that party had<br />

not assumed such a liability.<br />

As it turned out, the draft in dispute was the first draft the judge had ever seen.<br />

Hence, he did not understand how this three-party instrument functioned or why it<br />

was necessary when most of the merchants he knew used a two-party instrument<br />

such as a promissory note. The cost of such an unjustified over-protection of<br />

creditors-holders of drafts was quickly apparent. Very few merchants or their<br />

customers were willing to become parties to such a dangerous instrument.<br />

Consequently, a very useful three-party credit instrument such as the draft stopped<br />

being used in one of Costa Rica's principal credit markets for a good number of<br />

years.<br />

Conversely, underprotection of deserving third parties may reduce the number<br />

of willing potential market participants. A group of decisions by the Mexican<br />

Supreme Court accomplished this result, drastically reducing the number of<br />

protected third party creditors and purchasers of land. 4 " These decisions noted that a<br />

purchaser or creditor who acquired land or rights in rem could only be protected as a<br />

third party if he acted in good faith by doing a diligent search of the land registry<br />

records. 9 However, to do a diligent search, the third party had to examine the entire<br />

chain of title, from the first to the very last recording of the parcel, and the chain or<br />

"successive tract" had to be unbroken. Given the serious difficulties of searching<br />

most land records at the time of these decisions, very few purchasers or creditors<br />

could have qualified as protected third parties-especially with respect to properties<br />

with long or complicated title chains. Similarly, many developing nations still deny<br />

protection to contracting parties and to parties who acquired rights based upon their<br />

contracts, if those contracts did not fulfill certain ad solemnitatem (solemn)<br />

requirements. This is true regardless of whether one of or both of the parties<br />

performed their part of the bargain, or acted in reliance on the other party's promise<br />

of performance."<br />

2. The Wrong Choice of Protection<br />

Similar difficulties and negative consequences are apparent with the manner in<br />

which the law or its adjudicators have protected creditors. Consider, for example,<br />

the creditor remedy known as "apremio corporal" 5 popular in Costa Rica during a<br />

good part of the twentieth century until it was abrogated as unconstitutional." This<br />

remedy entailed the imprisonment of defaulting debtors, with its purpose to bring<br />

about certainty to its commercial and consumer credit market. The reasoning<br />

behind this remedy was callous but straightforward: if many debtors ordinarily<br />

48. For a translation and discussion of these decisions, see Boris Kozolchyk, The Mexican Land<br />

Registry: A Critical Evaluation, 12 ARIz. L. REV. 308, 336-38 (1970).<br />

49. Id. at 336.<br />

50. See BORIS KOZOLCHYK, LA CONTRATACION COMERCIAL EN EL DERECHO COMPARADO 214-52<br />

(2006).<br />

51. See COD. COM. art. 568 (1964) (now abrogated); COD. CIV. arts. 1002-1003 (1888) (now<br />

abrogated).<br />

52. Ley de Jurisdicci6n Constitucional No. 7135, La Gaceta No. 198, art. 113 (1989) (amended in La<br />

Gaceta No. 212 on Nov. 9, 1989), available at http://www.asamblea.go.crley/leyes/7000/7135.doc. For a<br />

discussion of the apremio corporal prior to its abrogation in Costa Rica, see Kozolchyk, supra note 21, at<br />

259-60.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 742 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURED LENDING AND ITS POVERTY REDUCTION EFFECT<br />

default in their credit obligations and most of them fear imprisonment, why not<br />

legislate the defaulting debtors' imprisonment? Thus, the Costa Rican legislature<br />

authorized an action that resulted in debtors' imprisonment for a period of two<br />

months to two years, unless the debtor complied with a court order to pay the debt<br />

or return the collateral.<br />

Contrary to the belief among legislators and judges that if this remedy were<br />

deemed unconstitutional Costa Rica's credit system would collapse, 53 no collapse<br />

occurred even though the sanction was rarely enforced. What happened instead was<br />

that creditors continued to extend credit, albeit at ever-increasing rates of interest.<br />

When a researcher asked one of the bailiffs-who roamed the city of San Jose<br />

looking for defaulting debtors- why he reported that no debtors were found after<br />

the most perfunctory of searches, his answer was revealing: if this sanction were<br />

enforced, most Costa Ricans, including the politicians who enacted it and the judges<br />

in charge of applying it, would all wind up in jail. 4<br />

3. Factors in the Choice of the Right Third Parties and Their Protection<br />

As illustrated by the wrong choices of protected third parties, for the legal<br />

choice to be effected properly, the lawmaker or adjudicator must fully understand<br />

the transaction in question-especially its purpose, its mechanics, and the reasonable<br />

expectations of participants. Only with this understanding is the lawmaker or<br />

adjudicator in a position accurately to assess the good faith standards used to<br />

measure the parties' performance and their qualifications for protection.<br />

The same is true with respect to the determination of the proper protection of<br />

third parties. As discussed earlier, it is not enough to invoke the truism of legal<br />

certainty and simply assume either that credit will necessarily be granted to those<br />

merchants who can exhibit a legally enforceable title, or that a penal enforcement of<br />

contract rights will generate larger volumes of consumer or micro-credit. Even if<br />

title is an important component of real estate-based credit, how effective a<br />

component will it be if courts adopt a standard of good faith that disqualifies most<br />

purchasers or creditors from the protection of the registry? A successful protection<br />

of creditors and debtors depends upon the manner in which the lawmakers and<br />

adjudicators handle the legal and socioeconomic facts that surround commercial and<br />

consumer lending.<br />

53. In a conversation with the Author during October 1968, the late Justice Ulises Odio of the Costa<br />

Rican Supreme Court expressed his constitutional misgivings but pointed to data that indicated that more<br />

than one thousand debtors in the city of San Jose (whose population was then approximately 250,000) were<br />

imprisoned for apremio corporal. Interview with Ulises Odio, Costa Rica Supreme Court, in San Jose,<br />

Costa Rica (Oct. 1968). Yet a field study of actual arrests conducted by team members of the <strong>Law</strong> Reform<br />

Project, under the Author's direction, showed that no more than four debtors were actually in jail for this<br />

action. The remainder in the Justice's printout were reported by the respective bailiffs as "not found" in<br />

their residences or places of business.<br />

54. Kozolchyk, Toward a Theory, supra note 46, at 731 n.183.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 743 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:727<br />

IV. LEGAL FACTS OF SECURED LENDING AND THEIR GUIDING<br />

PRINCIPLES<br />

A. The Universality of Effective Secured Lending Practice and Its Principles<br />

Secured lending has proven its effectiveness in improving a country's GDP as<br />

well as in reducing its poverty. By now, the secured lending practices that lead to<br />

commercial and consumer credit at reasonable rates of interest have been<br />

sufficiently tested in many of the world financial marketplaces, thus enabling the<br />

distillation of their guiding legal principles and formulas for creditor and debtor<br />

protection. Moreover, as with other commercial transactions, some key practices<br />

and legal principles of secured lending have gained universality.<br />

The universality of some of its practices results from the inherently limited<br />

methods that can be used by lenders when extending secured credit to strangers. The<br />

inherent limitation of effective practices is caused by the cooperative nature of<br />

commerce in general and of lending in particular. Accordingly, "winner take all,<br />

loser take none" as well as bad faith practices are incompatible with secured lending,<br />

as is the lack of transparency vis-A-vis third party creditors or purchasers. Since the<br />

advent of the contemporary financial marketplace, any commercial activity<br />

conducted with strangers requires as much reliable, timely, and easily accessible<br />

information as possible on the market participants. In the case of secured lending, if<br />

borrowers wish to rely on certain assets as the collateral that will help repay their<br />

borrowings, they must assure both known and unknown lenders of the availability of<br />

a desirable minimum, or cushion, of such assets.<br />

In secured lending practice it is thus indispensable to provide actual or potential<br />

lenders with a public, transparent, and accurate record of the borrowers'<br />

encumbered and unencumbered collateral. Any practice that results in hiding<br />

collateral or secured loans from the public eye is similarly incompatible with this<br />

transparency. Where the collateral is quickly perishable or depreciable in value, as is<br />

the case with most commercial assets, the creditor's ability to repossess and foreclose<br />

on these assets must also remain unimpeded, and cannot be tied up in lengthy court<br />

proceedings. Unless this is done, the creditor will lose the reassurance of his<br />

collateral cushion and will simply refuse to become a secured lender.<br />

It is for this reason that when I was asked by a Mexican NAFTA negotiator<br />

why Mexico's law of secured transactions had to resemble that of the United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

and Canada, my reply was that the proper question was not what law Mexico had to<br />

emulate, but whether Mexico in fact desired secured lending. If it did, its law had to<br />

be based on principles that reflected those tried and tested practices in active<br />

financial marketplaces, and were thus capable of universal usage. Where some of<br />

these practices are not followed-such as the practice of recording the security<br />

interest in a public registry-it is because lenders have their own system of private<br />

notice that is available to a small number of participants, but is unsuitable for<br />

markets with a larger number of participating strangers."<br />

55. For example, bankers in some markets resort to private informal organizations referred to in some<br />

Latin American countries as "risk clearing" offices (centrales de riesgo) which allow them to exchange<br />

information on individual debtors' loans and payment or performance records. Such organizations do not<br />

create rights with regard to non-participating third parties such as other creditors or purchasers of debtors'<br />

assets. Neither can they assure the participants that all the rights in the debtors' collateral have been taken<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 744 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURED LENDING AND ITS POVERTY REDUCTION EFFECT<br />

B. The NLCIFT Principles<br />

The principles discussed hereafter informed the drafting of the Model <strong>Law</strong> on<br />

Secured Transactions adopted by the Organization of American <strong>State</strong>s (OAS) in<br />

2002" and by member nations in different versions, such as by Mexico 7 and Peru."<br />

Local versions of this Model <strong>Law</strong> are currently being considered for adoption by<br />

Guatemala, " El Salvador," 0 Honduras, Costa Rica, and Chile. 6 , As drafted by the<br />

National <strong>Law</strong> Center for Inter-American Free Trade (NLCIFT), these principles<br />

cover the creation, perfection, priority, and enforcement of security interests<br />

(garantias mobiliarias) in personal or moveable property.<br />

into account by the compilers of risk information. Mutatis mutandis, some countries resort to the<br />

conveyance of proprietary-fiduciary rights to certain creditors, or to their "retention of title rights," which<br />

are not recorded. This information is unavailable to other creditors or to potential creditors, considerably<br />

reducing the number of willing lenders.<br />

56. MODEL INTER-AMERICAN LAW ON SECURED TRANSACTIONS (2002) (adopted by the Sixth<br />

Inter-American Specialized Conference on Private International <strong>Law</strong> (known as CIDIP-VI, for its Spanish<br />

acronym) on February 8, 2002 (Final Act, 3(F), CIDIP-VI) [hereinafter Model <strong>Law</strong>]. Its name in Spanish<br />

is Ley Modelo Interamericana sobre Garantias Mobiliarias.<br />

57. Decreto por el que se reforman, adicionan y derogan diversas disposiciones de la Ley General de<br />

Tftulos y Operaciones de Crbdito, del C6digo de Comercio y de la Ley de Instituciones de Cr~dito [Decree<br />

Reforming, Amending, or Derogating Various Dispositions of the General <strong>Law</strong> on Negotiable Instruments<br />

and Credit Transactions, the Commercial Code, and the <strong>Law</strong> on Credit Institutions], Diario Oficial de la<br />

Federaci6n [D.O.]. 23 de mayo de 2000 (Mex.) [Reform <strong>Law</strong> of 2000]. and Decreto por el que se reforman,<br />

adicionan y derogan diversas disposiciones de la Ley General de Tftulos y Operaciones de Cr~dito, del<br />

C6digo de Comercio, de la Ley de Instituciones de Cridito, de la Ley del Mercado de Valores, de la Ley<br />

General de Instituciones y Sociedades Mutualistas de Seguros, de la Ley Federal de Instituciones de<br />

Fianzas y de la Ley General de Organizaciones y Actividades Auxiliares del Credito [Decree Reforming,<br />

Amending, or Derogating Various Dispositions of the General <strong>Law</strong> on Negotiable Instruments and Credit<br />

Transactions, the Commercial Code, the <strong>Law</strong> on Credit Institutions, the Securities Market <strong>Law</strong>, the<br />

General Amending, or Derogating Various Dispositions of the General <strong>Law</strong> on Negotiable Instruments<br />

and Credit Transactions, the Commercial Code, the <strong>Law</strong> on Credit Institutions, the Securities Market <strong>Law</strong>,<br />

the General <strong>Law</strong> on Insurance Companies, the Federal <strong>Law</strong> on Bonding Institutions, and of the General<br />

<strong>Law</strong> of Organizations and Activities Ancillary to Credit], Diario Oficial de la Federaci6n [D.O.], 13 de<br />

junio de 2003 (Mex.). While these decrees adopt some of the NLCIFT principles, others were disregarded<br />

much to the detriment of these important reforms.<br />

58. Ley de la Garantfa Mobiliaria, Ley 28677 (2006) (Peru). This law, however, does disregard<br />

important NLCIFT principles.<br />

59. See Vinicio Sic, Controlar6n mfis a cooperativas y ONG, May 2, 2006, available at<br />

http://www.sigloxxi.com/index.php?link=noticias&noticiaid=982.<br />

60. Professor Dale B. Furnish, a senior researcher at the NLCIFf, has been acting as an advisor to the<br />

government of El Salvador in its enactment of an OAS Model <strong>Law</strong>-inspired statute and expects enactment<br />

of it in the near future. The draft of this law is still in a preliminary stage and is not available for public<br />

discussion.<br />

61. The process of adoption of laws inspired in the OAS Model <strong>Law</strong> is, as of this writing, on its way in<br />

Honduras, Costa Rica, and Chile although at different stages of consideration. During October 2006, a<br />

drafting group was convened at the NLCIFT to prepare a revised draft of a Honduran decree-law to be<br />

submitted to the Honduran Congress during November 2006. In December 2006, members of the<br />

Honduran Supreme Court of Chamber of Commerce will also meet at the NLCIFT to discuss this draft<br />

and plan the drafting of regulations for a commercial-electronic registry. In the case of Costa Rica, during<br />

August 2006, President Oscar Arias appointed Ing. Jorge Woodbridge, Vice Minister of the Economy, to<br />

head a drafting commission of a Costa Rican law of secured transactions and a commercial electronic<br />

registry. Minister Woodbridge, in turn, appointed the legal advisors to the drafting commission; drafting is<br />

expected to commence in the immediate future. Chile's Ministry of the Treasury has approached the<br />

Chilean International Legal Center and the NLCIFT (its counterpart in the United <strong>State</strong>s) for advice in the<br />

drafting of a law of secured transactions for submission to the Chilean Congress in the near future.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 745 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:727<br />

The NLCIFT principles define commercial credit as an effective tool for<br />

economic development based upon the self-liquidating nature of its collateral. 6 2<br />

They describe a security interest as a "preferential right to possession or control of<br />

personal property [which] does not require that the debtor . . . have title to the<br />

personal property collateral ... ,,63 As discussed earlier, since this right is not of<br />

ownership, it can coexist with other possessory rights. In addition, the personal or<br />

moveable property that can be collateral must be open in number and can be present<br />

or future, tangible or intangible.'<br />

According to the principles, "[s]ecurity interests may be created by contract or<br />

by law." 65 However, to perfect a security interest vis-A-vis third parties, other<br />

requirements must be met, especially the requirement of giving functional notice to<br />

66<br />

these parties. The concept of functional notice includes either the creditor's<br />

possession in the case of the possessory pledge or a public notice system one of<br />

whose purposes is to eliminate secret liens. 67<br />

The principles strongly recommend the adoption of a registry system, in which<br />

all known or future security devices become part of a unitary security interest,<br />

thereby facilitating the ranking of priorities mostly based upon the rule of first to<br />

file, first in right. 6 Registration should be inexpensive, and should take place in a<br />

public registry that is easily accessible to third parties, regardless of nationality or<br />

economic sector (if at all possible by electronic means). In standardized fashion, the<br />

filing should contain only the essential data to identify the parties and the amount of<br />

the loan or line of credit and collateral-consistent with the needs of actual and<br />

potential third parties to discover all recorded liens against the debtor's assets.<br />

Generic descriptions of collateral such as inventory or accounts receivable should<br />

suffice. The registry should be indexed generally by the debtor's name and, only<br />

exceptionally, by the serial number of the goods.<br />

"A 'purchase money', or 'acquisition' security interest should take priority, to<br />

the extent that the credit provided is used directly to acquire the collateral, over<br />

prior existing perfected security interests in the same kind of collateral, as an<br />

incentive to those wishing to provide timely, valuable and needed loans and as a<br />

safeguard against the monopolization and immobilization of the collateral available<br />

by one or more secured creditors." 69 Perfection of a purchase money security<br />

interest should require-in addition to the appropriate filing-a special notice to<br />

pre-existing security interests.<br />

Taking into account the importance of consumer purchases as the originators of<br />

the stream of income that underlies commercial lending, a buyer in the ordinary<br />

course of business takes free of a perfected security interest created by his seller,<br />

even when the buyer may know of that security interest. However, "if the sale<br />

occurs outside the ordinary course of business, then the buyer takes subject to the<br />

security interest even if he pays a fair purchase price. '<br />

62. See NLCIFT Principles, supra note 22, princ. 1.<br />

63. Id. princ. 2.<br />

64. Id. princ. 3.<br />

65. Id. princ. 4.<br />

66. Id. princs. 5, 6, 7.<br />

67. Id.<br />

68. NLCIFT Principles, supra note 22.<br />

69. Id. princ. 8.<br />

70. Id. princ. 9.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 746 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURED LENDING AND ITS POVERTY REDUCTION EFFECT<br />

Self-liquidation of the security interests requires that repossession of the<br />

collateral and foreclosure take place by means of contractual and extrajudicial<br />

enforcement. The principles strongly suggest adoption of an enforcement mechanism<br />

that "confers upon the creditor or agreed-upon fiduciary the power to repossess or<br />

retain and foreclose on the collateral privately or by means of a highly expeditious<br />

judicial foreclosure." 7<br />

Extrajudicial enforcement without breach of peace and subject to subsequent<br />

judicial review is gaining increasing acceptance by legislators and legal<br />

commentators throughout the developing world. The Supreme Court of Mexico,<br />

for example, has upheld the constitutionality of an extrajudicial remedy associated<br />

with the Fideicomiso de Garantia, the Mexican version of the United <strong>State</strong>s deed of<br />

trust." In addition, the Costa Rican Supreme Court has validated the legality of a<br />

Fideicomiso de Garantia much along the lines of its Mexican counterpart. 7 " Highly<br />

respected constitutional law scholars, including one of the drafters of the<br />

Guatemalan constitution, concur on the constitutionality of the extrajudicial<br />

remedies of the proposed draft of the Guatemalan law of secured transactions. 75<br />

Because bankruptcy laws are often used as devices to evade debt collection in<br />

many developing nations-except where the bankruptcy law in question reflects<br />

contemporary creditor and debtor protection legislative trends-the principles<br />

recommend the exclusion of perfected security interests from the bankruptcy<br />

76<br />

estate. This is also a World Bank recommendation. 77 Exceptionally, where the<br />

71. Id. princ. 10.<br />

72. See, e.g., <strong>Law</strong> Amending the Civil Code, Notarial <strong>Law</strong>, and Other <strong>Law</strong>s art. 151j (Jan. 1, 2003)<br />

(Slovk.) (amending the Civil Code of 1964) (providing that creditor may not agree with debtor on the<br />

appropriation of the collateral prior to default). By contrast, no prohibition of the Pactum Commissorium<br />

exists after the default. Id.; accord UNMIK Regulation No. 2001/5, art. 19.12 (Kosovo). For Eastern<br />

European doctrinal opinions on the legality of the Pactum, see Ganka Ivanova, Bulgaria, in CTR. FOR INT'L<br />

LEG. STUD., INTERNATIONAL SECURED TRANSACTIONS 35 (2003) (stating that "acceptance of<br />

encumbered assets in satisfaction of the secured obligation is provided by the Civil Procedure Code in<br />

favor of the mortgagee or the pledgee under court foreclosure"). See also Chrysta Bdn, Hungary, in<br />

INTERNATIONAL SECURED TRANSACTIONS, supra, at 29. She writes that "following default, the secured<br />

creditor may propose to accept the encumbered assets in full or in partial satisfaction of the secured<br />

obligation. A pre-default agreement that automatically vests ownership of the encumbered assets in the<br />

secured creditor on default is null and void and unenforceable." The Author is indebted to NLCIFT staff<br />

member Marek Dubovec for supplying the above sources.<br />

73. For a discussion of this decision, see Dale Beck Furnish, El Debido Proceso y Derecho de<br />

Audiencia en la Ejecuci6n Contra de los Bienes del Deudor en los Estados Unidos Mexicanos y los Estados<br />

Unidos de Amrica: Un Andlisis Comparado, 17 EL FORO 119 (Barra Mexicana, Colegio de Abogados,<br />

Mdxico, 2004).<br />

74. Vistamarina, Vimasa S.A., Banco BCT Panama, y Banco de San Jos6 S.A., 00005-F-2003, 02-<br />

000086-0004-CI, 15:10, Sala Primera Civil Costa Rica (Jan. 15, 2003). I am grateful to Lic. Joaquin Picado,<br />

staff member of the NLCIFT, for the text of this important opinion.<br />

75. E-mail from Lic. Carlos Molina Mencos, Doctor en Derecho, Molina Mencos, Pineda y Asociados<br />

to Boris Kozolchyk, Director, National <strong>Law</strong> Center for Inter-American Free Trade (Jan. 6, 2005) (on file<br />

with author).<br />

76. See NLCIFT Principles, supra note 22, princ. 11.<br />

77. WORLD BANK & INT'L FIN. CORP., DOING BUSINESS IN 2006, at 67, available at<br />

http://www.doingbusiness.org/documents/DoingBusines2006_fullreport.pdf ("Reformers in poor countries<br />

would do better to focus on improving foreclosure of secured debt outside of bankruptcy, thus reducing<br />

reliance on the courts"); see also Kenneth W. Dam, Credit Markets, Creditors' Rights and Economic<br />

Development 26 (John M. Olin L. & Econ. Working Paper No. 281, 2006), available at<br />

http://www.law.uchicago.edu/<strong>Law</strong>econfWkngPprs-251-300/287.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 747 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:727<br />

bankruptcy takes the form of a business reorganization, collateral may become part<br />

of the bankruptcy estate-subject to the exclusive jurisdiction of the bankruptcy<br />

court to confirm the perfection of the security interest and establish its priority<br />

against the claims of other creditors-to determine the extent and value of the<br />

security interest, and ultimately also to decide whether the collateral is essential to a<br />

feasible reorganization that will protect valid security interests.<br />

V. CONCLUSIONS AND A CORRECTIVE STRATEGY<br />

The proposition that the financial plight of the poor in developing nations is<br />

hopeless deserves reconsideration in light of the repeated findings on the impact of<br />

commercial and consumer credit at reasonable rates of interest upon economic<br />

growth and reduction of poverty. Similarly, the conclusion that the massive<br />

distribution of legal titles to real or personal property is a necessary and sufficient<br />

condition to economic development also deserves reconsideration. At best, it may<br />

be a necessary but not a sufficient condition for certain-mostly real estate<br />

secured-loans. The transition from a micro to a commercial loan requires from<br />

either real or personal property collateral more than simple ownership or title: it<br />

requires self-liquidation and everything associated with this essential feature of the<br />

commercial loan.<br />

However, a corrective strategy for making commercial and consumer credit<br />

available at reasonable rates of interest in developing nations by adopting an open<br />

system of secured lending is still a work in progress. Much depends upon special<br />

features of the business and legal cultures of the country in question and upon the<br />

answers to critical legal and socioeconomic questions, such as: how valuable are its<br />

goods and services in local and international markets; how large is its consumer and<br />

borrowers' class; how skilled and educated are its craftsmen acting as small- and<br />

medium-sized businesses; how picaresque or tricky are the business practices<br />

associated with credit sales or with purchase money loans; how picaresque or tricky,<br />

or honest and reliable are its accounting practices (can lenders truly rely on what<br />

appears on financial statements?); how reliable are its collateral value appraisals or<br />

commercial insurance; how corrupt is its administration of justice; are there<br />

knowledgeable and honest bankruptcy trustees; are creditors' committees truly<br />

representative and trustworthy; how developed and reliable are its means of<br />

communication; and how dependable and costly are its transportation, warehousing<br />

and communications systems? These, and other variables, can become responsible<br />

for the viability of an OAS Model <strong>Law</strong>-inspired statute and the rapidity of its<br />

success.<br />

The experience with commercial lending in Latin America suggests some<br />

common normative problems whose solution deserves consideration as part of a<br />

successful strategy. These are:<br />

1. A secured lending law ought not be treated as an isolated legal enactment.<br />

Its success depends upon the enactment of equally effective and market-sensitive<br />

laws of bankruptcy, insolvency, electronic commerce (including an electronic registry<br />

of security interests in personal and real property) and more functional (and less<br />

formalistic) laws of contracts, negotiable instruments, and documents of title.<br />

Otherwise, whatever legal protection of third party creditors is obtained through the<br />

law of secured transactions will be lost by a "loose" or otherwise non-existing<br />

bankruptcy or e-commerce law. Similarly, whatever transactional speed and lower<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 748 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURED LENDING AND ITS POVERTY REDUCTION EFFECT<br />

cost of operation is achieved by the law of secured transactions will be lost by<br />

imposition of costly formalities by the law of contracts, negotiable instruments,<br />

documents of title, or by the laws that govern the notarial or governmental<br />

formalities of these and other transactions.<br />

2. As was done in the case of Guatemala and HondurasT-and will hopefully<br />

be done in Costa Rica and Chile-a careful evaluation of the most valuable and<br />

liquid collateral in the marketplace should precede the drafting of the provisions on<br />

perfection, priority and enforcement of security interest. For example, assuming the<br />

agricultural nature of such collateral in Guatemala and Honduras, perfection,<br />

priority, and enforcement rules should take into account the ad hoc type of<br />

documents or electronic records, ones that could convey rights to the collateral in<br />

question to bankers and purchasers in major spot and futures markets for the goods<br />

in question. 79<br />

3. Best practice guides should be developed and their use carefully monitored.<br />

Training and regular monitoring of performance should apply not only to secured<br />

lenders and borrowers, but also to the financial statement and reporting practices of<br />

accountants, appraisers, and business inspectors-whether they are acting as the<br />

parties' staff or independent contractors. The importance of reliable financial<br />

statements and certifications of value -particularly with regard to the required<br />

amount of collateral-cannot be overstated, especially in a picaresque business<br />

culture.<br />

4. <strong>Law</strong>yers, judges, registrars, mediators, and arbitrators should be trained in<br />

the market and third party protection-sensitive interpretation and administration of<br />

the secured transactions, bankruptcy, e-commerce, contracts, and registry laws.<br />

78. See Draft Guatemalan <strong>Law</strong> arts. 27-29; Draft Honduran <strong>Law</strong> arts. 36-38.<br />

79. See, e.g., Marek Dubovec, Commodity Contracts as Hedging and Security Tools (NLCIFT<br />

Occasional Paper, 2006) (on file with author and the NLCIFT).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 749 2006-2007


HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 750 2006-2007


Securitization in Israel<br />

SHALOM LERNER*<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. IN T R O D U CT IO N .................................................................................................. 75 1<br />

II. SECURITIZATION OF MORTGAGES IN ISRAEL .................................................. 753<br />

A . D escrip tion ................................................................................................... 753<br />

B. Securitization as an Assignment of Rights ................................................ 755<br />

C. Registration of the A ssignm ent ................................................................... 757<br />

D . N otice to the D ebtors ................................................................................... 758<br />

E . The B ank as Trustee .................................................................................... 759<br />

III. MAKING THE SECURITY INTERESTS AVAILABLE TO THE SPV ...................... 759<br />

IV . SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS ......................................................................... 764<br />

I. INTRODUCTION<br />

Securitization is a financing instrument that has been used in the West for many<br />

years. In transactions of this kind, a business that has many debtors sells all or some<br />

of the indebtedness of its debtors to a third party. These debts are repaid in monthly<br />

installments to the third party over many years, and the third party pays the seller a<br />

lump sum. The third party, the buyer, is usually a corporation created specifically<br />

for the purpose of the securitization transaction. This corporation has no business<br />

history, and the certificate of incorporation prohibits any future transactions, apart<br />

from the securitization transaction for which the corporation was created. This<br />

designated corporate entity, generally known as a special purpose vehicle (SPV),<br />

issues debentures or stock to raise money on the capital market. From the legal<br />

perspective, the issuance of debentures on the stock exchange constitutes a loan.<br />

The SPV borrows money from the public and creates a security interest in the only<br />

asset it owns-the financial rights it acquired from the seller. As in other issuances<br />

of debentures, the security interest is created by appointing a trustee. In some cases,<br />

the money is raised on the stock exchange through the issuance of stock. Either way,<br />

Professor of <strong>Law</strong>, Bar Ilan University, Israel.<br />

Hebrew University, Jerusalem, Israel (1981).<br />

LL.B, Bar lan University, Israel (1975); S.J.D,<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 751 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:751<br />

the SPV uses the money borrowed or raised to pay the seller for the interests it<br />

acquires.<br />

As mentioned, the SPV's certificate of incorporation bars the SPV from<br />

transacting any other business other than the purchase of financial assets from a<br />

specific seller; these are the only assets that the SPV owns. Therefore, the SPV is<br />

not expected to post any financial losses or have any new creditors. Given the low<br />

risk involved in SPVs, they normally receive a relatively high credit rating, which<br />

facilitates the distribution of SPV stock or debentures.<br />

In addition to the sale agreement, the seller and the SPV also execute a service<br />

agreement. The SPV has no employees and is unable to collect the debts it acquired<br />

from the seller independently. The seller, on the other hand, is specialized in its<br />

field, has communication channels with its debtors, and has an efficient collection<br />

system. The seller and the SPV enter a service agreement whereby the seller<br />

provides the SPV with collection services in consideration of an agreed payment.<br />

Under this agreement, the seller continues to collect the debts, holds the money in<br />

trust for the SPV, and transfers the money to the SPV as soon as possible. This trust<br />

structure bars the seller's creditors from arguing that the SPV is an ordinary creditor,<br />

rather than simply a holder of a property right.<br />

The seller does not issue stock or debentures to the investors directly, because<br />

this would expose the investors to the risks inherent in the seller's general and<br />

ongoing operations and create competition between the investors and the seller's<br />

other creditors. The SPV isolates the seller's rights against the debtors from the<br />

seller's other assets, and prevents the SPV's ordinary creditors from collecting<br />

against these rights.<br />

Securitization started in the mortgage sectors of Great Britain and the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s. These transactions were called "secondary mortgages," rather than primary<br />

mortgages, which are secured loans granted by banks or other lenders to home<br />

buyers. Securitization then spread to other businesses that had financial means or<br />

long term accounts receivables. Examples of securitized assets include the<br />

indebtedness owed to suppliers by issuers of credit card transactions and the<br />

financial rights of an industrial plant against its existing and future customers.<br />

The first securitization transactions in Israel took place a few years ago, mostly<br />

in the mortgage sector. The first part of this paper will focus on the securitization of<br />

mortgages and will also explain the problems characteristic of such transactions. The<br />

second part of this paper describes the standard structure of securitization<br />

transactions in Israel, analyzes them from a legal perspective, and addresses<br />

additional questions, such as registration and notice to borrowers. The third part of<br />

this paper deals with an issue of great practical significance: the need to register the<br />

SPV as a mortgagee in order to perfect the mortgage.<br />

Securitization is seen in Israel in two other areas. First, automobile leasing<br />

companies and local governments have recently started securitizing their accounts<br />

receivables. Leasing companies lease various assets, mainly cars, in consideration of<br />

monthly payments by the lessees, for an average period of three to five years.<br />

Several leasing companies started to securitize this indebtedness. This securitization<br />

takes place through an SPV. The SPV creates a buffer between the leasing company<br />

and the investors. The competition in the leasing industry in Israel is fierce, and a<br />

leasing company might face financing problems if it is unable to lease all of its fleet.<br />

These problems do not affect the SPV, which is not exposed to the company's<br />

general business operations; the SPV only acquires the rights that the leasing<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 752 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURITIZATION IN ISRAEL<br />

company has against existing customers. At the end of 2004, a small leasing<br />

company collapsed after the controlling shareholder embezzled the money he had<br />

received from lessees, which the leasing company was supposed to hold in trust for<br />

the SPV. This affair exposed the need for appropriate monitoring and slowed down<br />

the securitization process in the leasing industry. The investors, however, did not<br />

suffer any materially adverse effect and continued to receive the leasing fees paid by<br />

lessees thereafter.<br />

The second sector in which securitization transactions have become popular in<br />

Israel is local government. The local government initiates development programs<br />

and then requires financing that exceeds the income it generates from both taxes and<br />

the contribution of the central government. Until recently, the exclusive source of<br />

financing used in these cases was loans from commercial banks. A few years ago,<br />

many local governments encountered financial difficulties, causing the banks to<br />

increase their interest rates. Consequently, the local governments started to raise<br />

money on the capital market. A strong local government can issue municipal bonds<br />

without collateral. Several local governments have recently securitized their income<br />

from the municipal tax revenue expected over the next few years, or on the future<br />

income from real estate, such as parking lots. Once local governments discovered<br />

this alternative method of financing, the banks reduced their interest rates almost<br />

immediately.'<br />

As noted, securitization only started in Israel a few years ago. The relevant<br />

legislation is scarce, and most problems that emerge in this field must therefore be<br />

resolved through the general body of law. The most important law in this context is<br />

the 1969 Transfer of Obligations <strong>Law</strong>. There is still no case law addressing<br />

securitization, except for one case relating to the securitization of rights against<br />

lessees of automobiles. 2 The securitization transactions that took place in Israel in<br />

the last few years were not as complex as those implemented in other countries. The<br />

Tel Aviv Stock Exchange has yet to issue debentures or shares of SPVs. When SPVs<br />

were being created, the players did not raise money from the general public through<br />

the stock exchange, but rather from institutional investors through private channels.<br />

It seems, however, that the first public issuance in the mortgage sector is<br />

forthcoming.<br />

II.<br />

SECURITIZATION OF MORTGAGES IN ISRAEL<br />

A. Description<br />

In Israel, mortgage banks are not authorized to provide general banking<br />

services, only loans to the public for the purpose of buying real estate. Most of these<br />

banks are subsidiaries of commercial banks. Recently, two mortgage banks were<br />

merged into their parent companies, so that the mortgage area is now managed by a<br />

separate division within the bank.<br />

1. I believe that the securitization of future tax earnings by these governments gives rise to serious<br />

legal issues, because the debtors whose indebtedness is being transferred are unspecified debtors who will<br />

reside in that locality in the future. However, that issue extends beyond the scope of this paper.<br />

2. CC 2146/04, Civil Motions 8120/04, Deloitte & Teuche (Israel) Brightman Almagor Trusts Ltd. v.<br />

Israel Discount Bank Ltd., Takdin, DC 2005(3) 10575.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 753 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:751<br />

The banks lend money to the public for the purchase of real estate-homes in<br />

most cases. Against the loan, the bank receives a mortgage on the borrower's<br />

property, usually the real estate acquired with the loan. In a securitization<br />

transaction, the mortgage bank sells rights it has against specific borrowers to an<br />

SPV which is created for the securitization transaction. Under the rules of the Bank<br />

of Israel (Israel's central bank), a mortgage bank may not sell only strong loans-i.e.,<br />

loans with a low probability of default-and maintain only the weak loans, because<br />

this might undermine the bank's stability. The bank must therefore sell the SPV a<br />

portfolio representative of all its borrowers. An exhibit attached to the sale<br />

agreement specifies the names of the borrowers whose obligations to make future<br />

payments are sold to the SPV. In the standard securitization transaction in Israel,<br />

the mortgage bank and SPV stipulate that if a borrower defaults, the SPV will have<br />

no recourse against the bank.<br />

The SPV has no tools to handle the logistics of loans. The bank thus provides<br />

these services for the SPV for an agreed fee. The services include management of<br />

the loans, ongoing communications with the borrowers, collection of the debts, and<br />

foreclosure of the mortgages. Since the sale agreement transfers the ownership of<br />

the loans portfolio to the SPV, the bank acts as an agent for the SPV. The service<br />

agreement provides, generally, that the bank will collect the money from the<br />

borrowers on behalf of the SPV and transfer the money collected to the SPV on<br />

agreed dates.<br />

Securitization offers the banks various advantages. The immediate payment<br />

enables the bank to expand its business. There is also an advantage to the bank's<br />

accounting, since the loans no longer appear on the balance sheet. The institutional<br />

entities that finance the SPV are corporations with high liquidity and substantial<br />

resources-such as pension funds and insurance companies-that are always looking<br />

for new investment avenues. Under the securitization agreement, the mortgage<br />

bank acts as a mediator in the financing sector and entitles the investors to<br />

repayment of the loans and the interest acquired by the borrowers.<br />

The SPV and its lenders, the debenture holders, want to make sure that events<br />

that might take place after the transaction will not have an adverse effect on the<br />

future cash flow from the borrowers. The SPV is concerned about the following<br />

scenarios:<br />

Insolvency of the bank. The goal here is to prevent a receiver or an<br />

administrator from taking possession of the money paid by the borrowers. The SPV<br />

seeks to stop this money from becoming part of the receivership asset pool, and to<br />

make sure that it both belongs to the SPV and is available to the debenture holders.<br />

The SPV also wants to ensure that the bank's creditors cannot impose liens on the<br />

money owed by the borrowers.<br />

A conflicting transaction by the borrower. The borrower might execute a<br />

transaction in violation of the mortgage with the bank, such as a transfer of<br />

ownership or any other right in the property to a third party. The bank will prevail<br />

over such competition because it is named as mortgagee in the Land Registry. The<br />

SPV seeks to have the same priority.<br />

Insolvency of the borrower. Before the securitization, the bank is a secured<br />

creditor, and has priority over the borrower's other creditors upon insolvency. This<br />

priority is guaranteed by the mortgage, which enables the bank to foreclose on the<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 754 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURITIZATION IN ISRAEL<br />

mortgage directly without having to first obtain court approval.' The SPV seeks the<br />

same protection.<br />

B. Securitization as an Assignment of Rights<br />

To check whether the SPV and the investors can accomplish these goals, the<br />

transaction between the bank and the SPV must be analyzed in accordance with the<br />

set of laws governing it. To this end, I will now provide a brief review of the laws<br />

regulating the assignment of rights.<br />

Generally, a creditor can sell his rights or use them as a security interest. That<br />

is, a creditor can either sell his rights or take a loan, submitting his rights against his<br />

debtors to the lender as collateral. In a sale of rights, as in the sale of movable or<br />

immovable property, the object of sale ceases to be the property of the seller, and<br />

becomes that of the buyer. Ownership of the right transfers to the assignee even<br />

without any notice to the debtor. 4<br />

The other transaction, in terms of security interests, is known as a pledge,<br />

meaning "a charge on property as security for an obligation." 5 In the law of Transfer<br />

of Obligations it is called a "transfer of a right by way of a charge", 6 In a sale of<br />

rights, the assignee is the buyer; whereas in an assignment by way of a charge, the<br />

assignee is a secured creditor, and the assignor's other creditors are unsecured<br />

creditors. Under the laws regulating security interests, a secured creditor prevails<br />

over all other creditors if its security interest is registered in a public registry. 7<br />

After the assignment, a creditor of the assignor cannot impose a lien on the<br />

transferred rights. In a true sale, the assignor is no longer the owner of the rights,<br />

which are henceforth no longer exposed to the imposition of liens by the assignor's<br />

creditors.' An assignee who is a secured creditor and has registered the security<br />

interest also prevails over the holder of a lien.<br />

Insolvency of the assignor is not supposed to have any adverse effect on the<br />

assignee. The assignor's receiver cannot add the assigned rights to the general asset<br />

pool, because these rights have become the property of the assignee. This rule<br />

applies even if the payment of the assigned debts is due only after the receivership<br />

order is handed down against the assignor. 9 The same is true of an assignment by<br />

way of a charge.<br />

3. Pledges <strong>Law</strong>, 5727-1967, 17 LSI 44 (1967)(Isr.) § 17 (stating "a pledge deposited as specified in<br />

section 4(2) and serving as security for an obligation towards a banking institution, within the meaning of<br />

the Bank of Israel <strong>Law</strong>, 5714-1954)[sic], can be realized by such institution without an order as aforesaid").<br />

4. CA 5578/93 Nadav v. Sargovi [1995] IsrSC 49(2) 459, 470 (holding that under Israeli law, ownership<br />

of the right transfers upon execution of the assignment agreement, and there is even no need to notify the<br />

debtor in order for the transaction to be completed).<br />

5. Pledges <strong>Law</strong> § l(a).<br />

6. Transfer of Obligations <strong>Law</strong>, 5729-1969, 23 LSI 277 (1968-69) (Isr.) § 1(b).<br />

7. Pledges <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 3, § 4(3); Companies Ordinance (New Version), (1983) (lsr.) § 178.<br />

8. CA 165/75 Levinger v. Ramat Gan Zoology Park Ltd., IsrSC 30(2) 75: CA 568/85 Bank Hapoalim<br />

(Switzerland) Ltd. v. First International Bank of Israel's Trust Company Ltd., IsrSC 32(4) 507; CA 2328/97<br />

Kochavi v. Arenfeld, 53(2) 353.<br />

9. CA 142/70 Shmueli v. Receivers of the Iron Company Ltd., IsrSC 24(2) 446.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 755 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:751<br />

However, the status of the assignee as a buyer is better than the assignee's<br />

status as a secured creditor. For instance, the court has the power-as part of the<br />

process of helping a company under receivership to recover-to suspend the exercise<br />

of security interests, provided that the secured creditor's rights are adequately<br />

protected. ° Yet the court has no authority to violate, even temporarily, the rights of<br />

an assignee who purchased the company's rights against third parties. Also, if the<br />

rights are assigned via a security interest, the assignee must repay the assignor any<br />

money collected from the debtors in excess of the loan."<br />

It is not easy to define the criteria with which to distinguish between a true sale<br />

from a security interest. Israeli case law on this matter is scarce. According to the<br />

existing case law, if the assignment agreement provides that an assignor who is<br />

unable to collect the debt from the debtor has no recourse against the assignor, then<br />

the transaction is a true sale, and if the assignee can collect against the assignor, it is<br />

a security interest. 2<br />

Indeed, if under the assignment agreement, an assignee who is unable to collect<br />

the debt has no recourse against the assignor, the transaction fails to satisfy all the<br />

elements of the laws of security interests. Under the Pledges <strong>Law</strong> a security interest<br />

is incidental to the debt-it secures the debt but does not replace the debt.' 3 A<br />

lender who received a security interest and whose debt is not wholly satisfied may<br />

exercise the security interest and collect its debt from the proceeds, file a regular suit<br />

against the lender to repay the debt, or do both.' 4 That is, a lender that received a<br />

security interest may, at its discretion, seek repayment of the loan from the borrower<br />

without exercising the security interest. If the assignee may not sue the assignor,<br />

then their relationship is not one of lender and borrower. Israeli law does not<br />

recognize an in rem security interest, under which there is no duty upon the<br />

borrower to repay the debt. Parties cannot create such an interest in contract,<br />

because the list of property rights protected by law is finite-the courts are not<br />

authorized to recognize a property interest that was not recognized by the<br />

legislature."<br />

I will now analyze the securitization transaction under the principles governing<br />

the transfer of obligations. The bank has contractual rights under the loan<br />

agreements to receive various amounts of money from the borrowers and may assign<br />

these rights to the SPV. "The right of a creditor . . . is capable of being transferred<br />

without the consent of the debtor, unless its transferability is negated or restricted by<br />

10. Companies <strong>Law</strong>, 5759-1999, 44 LSI 1 (1999) (Isr.) § 350(b).<br />

11. See, e.g., Major's Furniture Mart Inc. v. Castle Credit Corp., 602 F. 2d 538, 542 (1978) (analyzing<br />

the <strong>Penn</strong>sylvania Code, which states that "[ilf the security agreement secures and indebtedness, the secured<br />

party must account to the debtor for any surplus, and unless otherwise agreed, the debtor is liable for any<br />

deficiency").<br />

12. See, e.g., CC 3113/88 Prinir Ltd. (In Receivership) v. Bank Leumi Ltd., IsrDC (unpublished) ("If<br />

this were an absolute assignment, then upon its execution, the assignor's obligations are terminated; but<br />

this transaction allows for the bank to collect against the assignor in case the assigned right is defaulted<br />

upon."); see also CA 3966/01 Yehoshua TBWA v. Bon Mart Millennium Ltd. (In Receivership), IsrSC<br />

57(4) 952; see generally S. Lerner, Assignment of Obligations, in LAW OF OBLIGATIONS-GENERAL PART<br />

284-90 (2002) (stating that recourse against the assignor does not necessarily mean the transaction is a<br />

security interest rather than a true sale).<br />

13. Pledges <strong>Law</strong> § 7.<br />

14. Id. § 23.<br />

15. See CA 46/74 Mordov v. Schechtman, IsrSC 29(1) 477 (regarding property rights as a finite list):<br />

accord J. WEISMAN, LAWS OF PROPERTY: GENERAL PART 75-87 (1993).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 756 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURITIZATION IN ISRAEL<br />

law, by the nature of the right or by agreement between the debtor and the<br />

6<br />

creditor.' Therefore, if the agreement between the borrower and the bank does<br />

not prohibit the latter from transacting in the rights, the bank may assign its rights<br />

against the borrowers to an SPV. In this transaction, the bank is the assignor, the<br />

SPV is the assignee, and the borrowers are the debtors. The outcome of the<br />

assignment is that the assignor ceases to be the debtor's creditor, and the assignee<br />

becomes the debtor's only creditor. After the agreement between the bank and the<br />

SPV is executed, the SPV is the creditor of the borrowers, who now have no<br />

obligation toward the bank. From a contractual perspective, the SPV becomes the<br />

borrowers' creditor-instead of the bank. From the perspective of property law, the<br />

SPV becomes the owner of the rights.<br />

As a creditor of the various borrowers, the SPV may assign its rights without<br />

their consent. The pledging of the rights to the investors who lend money to the<br />

SPV constitutes an additional assignment. But this assignment is by way of a charge.<br />

The issuance of debentures on the stock exchange is a loan that the SPV receives<br />

from the investors, and the SPV transfers the rights it has against the borrowers as a<br />

security interest.<br />

The assignment of the bank's rights to the SPV protects the latter from an<br />

exposure to any insolvency of the assigning bank or the imposition of a lien by one<br />

of its creditors. This protection also applies in the case of an assignment by way of a<br />

charge. However, as a purchaser, the rights of the SPV are better protected, as are<br />

the interests of its investors. In fact, it is in the bank's best interest to perform a true<br />

sale, because of accounting considerations. After a true sale the bank no longer<br />

needs to include the rights against the borrowers in its balance sheets, which in turn<br />

may improve its capital adequacy ratio.<br />

In mortgage securitizations in Israel, it is standard to include a provision that<br />

expressly stipulates that if the SPV is unable to collect the debt from the borrowers,<br />

the SPV will not be entitled to demand that the bank repay the entire principal-the<br />

money it paid to the bank for the assignment. Typically, the bank only assumes<br />

liability for a very small portion of the principal. Only a full right of recourse that<br />

would expose the bank to an obligation to repay the entire amount will be<br />

interpreted as a security interest transaction. The typical securitization transaction<br />

in Israel is structured as a true sale.<br />

C. Registration of the Assignment<br />

In case of bankruptcy or receivership, the interests of a secured creditor will not<br />

be protected unless the assignment has been registered. Section 97 of the<br />

Bankruptcy Ordinance stipulates the following:<br />

(a) Where a person has transferred existing or future rights to another and<br />

is subsequently adjudged bankrupt, the transfer shall be of no effect<br />

against the trustee as regards claims which were not settled before the<br />

commencement of the bankruptcy unless the transfer was registered at the<br />

time and in the manner prescribed by regulations.<br />

16. Transfer of Obligations <strong>Law</strong> § l(a).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 757 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:751<br />

(b) The provisions of subsection (a) shall not apply to a transfer of claims<br />

against debtors specified in the instrument of transfer and the due date of<br />

settlement of which coincides with or precedes the time of the transfer, or<br />

in existing or future rights under contracts specified in the instrument of<br />

transfer, or of rights the transfer of which is included in the transfer of a<br />

business in good faith and for consideration. 7<br />

Section 97 imposes a duty of registration with respect to a general assignment<br />

that does not specify the contracts to which the assignment applies or the names of<br />

the debtors. The registration requirement does not apply where the contracts or<br />

debtors are specified in the instrument of assignment." 8 If the names of the<br />

borrowers whose debts are assigned are adequately specified, the true sale<br />

transaction does not have to be registered. Typically, an addendum to the<br />

agreement between the bank and the SPV specifies the names of the borrowers and<br />

the dates of their contracts with the banks.<br />

D. Notice to the Debtors<br />

As a rule, the agreement between the bank and the SPV does not require the<br />

borrowers' consent. The laws governing the assignment of rights do not obligate the<br />

assignor or the assignee to notify the debtor of the assignment. However, notice to<br />

the borrowers of the assignment could strengthen the SPV's protection. A debtor<br />

may not raise claims against the assignee arising from other transactions he has with<br />

the assignor if these claims accrued after notice of the assignment was given. 9 Some<br />

borrowers, especially those who also have savings plans or provident funds at the<br />

bank, may also have various causes of action against the bank. Notification to the<br />

borrowers regarding the assignment protects the SPV against any new arguments<br />

that the borrowers may have against the bank.<br />

A special provision passed into law in 2003 with respect to the securitization of<br />

mortgages states the following: "Should a mortgage be registered under this Section,<br />

the transferring corporation shall immediately give notice of the transfer to the<br />

borrower and the owner of the real estate securing the registered mortgage." 20 The<br />

notice requirement applies regardless of whether the mortgage registry is amended.<br />

The purpose of the law is to protect the borrower/owner of the real estate that serves<br />

as mortgage in the case of securitization. The notice affects the protection granted<br />

by law to the borrower/owner, and therefore the borrower/owner must be notified.<br />

Under the laws of assignments, "[t]he transfer of a right does not alter the right<br />

or the conditions thereof." 2 ' Therefore, provisions allowing early mortgage payoff<br />

will remain in full force and effect. The duty to send the borrowers periodic reports<br />

no longer rests with the bank, but with the SPV. Such reporting is not an<br />

independent duty of the bank but an incidental duty to the ownership of the right<br />

17. Bankruptcy Ordinance (New Version), 5740-1980, 3 NV 131 (1981) (Isr.) § 97.<br />

18. Regarding the cancellation of a general, unregistered assignment, see CA 596/86 Yehudit Ben<br />

Zion v. Gorni-Trustee for the Assets of Yehoshua Ben Zion, IsrSC 43(2) 460.<br />

19. Transfer of Obligations <strong>Law</strong> § 2(c).<br />

20. Settlement in the <strong>State</strong> Economy (Amendments Designated to Accomplish the Budget and<br />

Economic Policy Goals for the Fiscal Year of 2003), 2002, § 46(b).<br />

21. Transfer of Obligations <strong>Law</strong> § 2(a).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 758 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURITIZATION IN ISRAEL<br />

against the borrowers, and the duty transfers to the SPV accordingly.<br />

service agreement, reporting will continue to be carried out by the bank.<br />

Under the<br />

E. The Bank as Trustee<br />

The bank and the SPV execute a service agreement under which-in<br />

consideration of an agreed fee-the bank will continue to collect the money from the<br />

borrowers, and transfer it to the SPV shortly thereafter. The bank might be liable<br />

toward the SPV if it is negligent in collecting the money. This liability has no effect<br />

on the classification of the assignment agreement as a true sale or as a security<br />

interest. Keeping the service agreement as separate from the sale agreement might<br />

help thwart any allegation that the transaction was not a true sale.<br />

From a property law standpoint, the money held by the bank is the property of<br />

the SPV. In one instance, Israel's Supreme Court expressed its opinion that where<br />

the debtor paid the debt to the assignor instead of the assignee, the assignor was<br />

holding the money in trust for the assignee. 22 The standard service agreement used<br />

in Israel expressly stipulates that the bank is a trustee for the issuer.<br />

The creditors of a trustee have no recourse against the assets held in trust. The<br />

Trust <strong>Law</strong> states: "Trust property shall not be distrained save for debts resting on<br />

that property or arising out of activities of the trust." 2 Thus, the bank's creditors<br />

have no access to the money that the bank holds in trust for the SPV: "A trust has<br />

effect vis-A-vis any person who knows or ought to know about it, and where a note<br />

has been entered under section 4, vis-A-vis the whole world." 2 If the bank is<br />

dissolved, the receiver might argue that the trust agreement between the bank and<br />

the SPV is not binding upon the receiver, because the receiver was not aware of its<br />

existence.<br />

In order to protect the trust, the following actions can be taken:<br />

a. Incorporating a provision in the service agreement that expressly states that<br />

the bank will hold the money obtained from the borrowers in trust for the issuer or<br />

the investors;<br />

b. Holding the money received in a separate trust account and prohibiting the<br />

bank from transacting in this money in any way-apart from a transfer to the SPV;<br />

c. Registering the transaction between the bank and the SPV with the<br />

Companies' Registrar. Such registration could inform third parties of the SPV's<br />

rights and thus satisfy the requirement regarding third parties' knowledge as<br />

required to protect the trust.<br />

III. MAKING THE SECURITY INTERESTS AVAILABLE TO THE SPV<br />

The underlying loan agreement between the bank and the borrower gives the<br />

bank a mortgage over the borrower's real estate. This mortgage is evidenced in the<br />

Land Registry and grants the bank priority over the other creditors if the borrower<br />

22. CA 4724/90 ESHET Finance Ltd. v. United Mizrahi Bank Ltd., IsrSC 46(3) 570, 577.<br />

23. Trust <strong>Law</strong>, 5739-1979, 33 LSI 154 (1978-79) (Isr.) § 3(b).<br />

24. Id. § 5.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 759 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:751<br />

becomes insolvent. Also, if the borrower executes a transaction that conflicts with<br />

the mortgage the bank will prevail. This section discusses the ways that the SPV can<br />

get such priority as well.<br />

Under the laws governing transfers of obligations, along with the assigned right,<br />

the assignee also receives incidental rights. Unless the parties expressly stipulate<br />

otherwise, incidental rights and obligations transfer along with the principal right<br />

that is being transferred. Section 5 of the Transfer of Obligations <strong>Law</strong> states:<br />

Subject to the transfer agreement, the transfer of a right includes<br />

any guarantee or charge given as security for it and any other<br />

right concomitant to the transferred right, as far as they are<br />

transferable; and the creditor shall, upon the demand of the<br />

transferee, do the acts necessary in order that the transfer of the<br />

said rights may be valid in all respects.'<br />

This provision implies that the security interest is transferable under the law,<br />

regardless of the consent of the debtor in the underlying transaction. 26 An<br />

assignment that does not include the security interests securing the right reduces the<br />

value of the transferred right. Requiring a debtor's consent conflicts with the key<br />

principle of the laws of transfer of obligations- that rights can be transferred swiftly<br />

without the debtor's consent. 7<br />

The SPV is therefore entitled to be the named mortgagee in the Land Registry,<br />

and may ask the Land Registry to amend the registration in accordance with Section<br />

87 of the Land <strong>Law</strong>. The 1974 Land Regulations (Fees)' stipulate the fee payable<br />

for such an amendment. Under Section 87 of the Land <strong>Law</strong>, a mortgage cannot be<br />

transferred if the underlying loan agreement between the bank and the borrower<br />

prohibits the transfer. 29 However, the language of most loan agreements in Israel<br />

does not include such prohibition. In practice, the Land Registrar does not check<br />

the terms of each loan agreement and makes do with a confirmation by the company<br />

and an affidavit drafted by its legal counsel certifying that "[under] the terms of the<br />

mortgage, the consent of the owner of the land is not required in order to transfer<br />

the mortgage. ' Once the Registry is amended, the SPV becomes the mortgagee<br />

and has the same legal status as the bank did prior to the transfer. The SPV's<br />

mortgage is considered a continuation of the original mortgage, rather than a new<br />

31<br />

one.<br />

25. Transfer of Obligations <strong>Law</strong> § 5.<br />

26. For example, the SPV will be assigned guarantees that third parties have made to secure the<br />

borrowers' loans.<br />

27. CA 886/97 Burstein v. Hudad, IsrSC 52(4) 68 (holding that the debtor's consent is not required in<br />

order to assign the incidental rights). This proposition is reflected in U.S. law, according to which a<br />

mortgage securing a specific debt transfers to the assignee to whom the debt is assigned, even if the<br />

assignee is unaware of the existence of the mortgage based on the documentation. See RESTATEMENT<br />

(THIRD) OF PROPERTY § 5.4 cmt. c (1997) (stating "the obligation will 'follow' the mortgage even if not<br />

expressly mentioned in any document of transfer .. .this section is designed to carry out the parties'<br />

intention even though they, through ignorance or inadvertence, have not fully documented it").<br />

28. The Land Regulations (Fees), 1974, add. § 2(b)(1).<br />

29 Land <strong>Law</strong>, 5729-1969, 23 LSI 283 (1968-69) (Isr.) § 87.<br />

30. Settlement in the <strong>State</strong> Economy <strong>Law</strong> § 46(a)(1).<br />

31. Motion 859/95, CC (TA) 1898/94 In Re Dov Fischler, Adv. v. Shekel Leasing Ltd., Takdin, DC<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 760 2006-2007


2007<br />

SECURITIZATION IN ISRAEL<br />

That said, an amendment of thousands of mortgage registrations involves a<br />

considerable fee, possibly hindering the use of securitization transactions. It is<br />

therefore important to understand the legal status of an SPV that decides not to<br />

amend the Registry, leaving the bank as the named mortgagee. This subject has not<br />

been addressed by the courts yet. It is my opinion that the SPV is a secured creditor,<br />

whether or not the Registry is amended to state that the SPV is the mortgagee<br />

instead of the bank.<br />

Section 5 of the Transfer of Obligations <strong>Law</strong> says that security interests that the<br />

assignor had transfer to the assignee as part of the assignment. The law adds that<br />

"the creditor shall, upon the demand of the transferee, do the acts necessary in order<br />

that the transfer of the said rights may be valid in all respects." 32 This language<br />

seems to indicate that various complementary actions are required in order to give<br />

the security interest full force and effect in the hands of the assignee. According to<br />

this reading, the assignee is secured by the security interest only after the Registry is<br />

amended. I argue that this interpretation is undesirable and should therefore be<br />

rejected.<br />

The mortgage transfers to the SPV under Section 5 and under the agreement<br />

between the bank and the SPV. At this point the SPV is the holder of an<br />

unregistered mortgage. In 1999, Israel's Supreme Court opined that the purchaser<br />

of real estate has a right in equity even before the Registry is amended to reflect the<br />

new ownership or before a warning (a "caveat," known in Hebrew as he'arat azhara)<br />

to third parties that a contract has been executed for the sale of the property is<br />

entered in the Registry. 33 Based on this logic, the Court prioritized a purchaser over<br />

a creditor of the seller that has a lien on the property.' This decision changed the<br />

previous precedent, according to which until the transaction was entered in the Land<br />

Registry, a purchaser of land was not considered to have a proprietary right but only<br />

a contractual right. In another decision, delivered toward the end of 2003, the court<br />

held that the equitable right that a buyer had before the transaction that was<br />

perfected by registration also protects such buyer against insolvency of the seller. 5<br />

The buyer has priority over the other creditors of the insolvent seller and is entitled<br />

to receive the title to the real estate. In other words, the execution of an agreement<br />

for the sale of real estate in and of itself gives the buyer priority, and the transacted<br />

real estate will not be part of the pool of assets available to the creditors.<br />

The above case law raises questions about the unregistered mortgage. The<br />

Supreme Court deduced the existence of an equitable right from Section 9 of the<br />

Land <strong>Law</strong>, which, in addition to sale transactions, also governs a covenant to register<br />

a mortgage. 36 The Supreme Court has not addressed this issue yet, and the district<br />

96(3) 3792.<br />

32 Transfer of Obligations <strong>Law</strong> § 5.<br />

33. CA 189/95 Bank Otsar Ha-Hayal v. Aharonov, IsrSC 53(4) 199.<br />

34. Id.<br />

35. CA 3911/01 Caspi v. Shlomo Ness as Trustee in A Creditor Workout for "Diyur La-Oleh", lsrSC<br />

56(6) 752.<br />

36. Land <strong>Law</strong> § 9 (stating "[wihere a person has undertaken to effect a transaction in immovable<br />

property, and before it is completed by registration he undertakes towards another person to effect a<br />

conflicting transaction, the right of the party to the first transaction shall prevail: Provided that if the party<br />

to the second transaction has acted in good faith and for consideration, and such transaction is registered<br />

while he is still in good faith, his right shall prevail.").<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 761 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:751<br />

courts have expressed varying views. 37 I agree with the approach that recognizes the<br />

enforceability of an unregistered mortgage. The case law supporting the other<br />

approach does not offer any theoretical basis for the distinction between the<br />

unregistered right of a buyer and the unregistered right of a mortgagee.<br />

The SPV's priority also arises from Section 4(3) of the Pledges <strong>Law</strong>. According<br />

to this Section: "A pledge shall be effective against other creditors of the debtor...<br />

upon the registration of the pledge in accordance with regulations made under this<br />

<strong>Law</strong>: Provided that against a creditor who knew or should have known of the pledge<br />

it shall be effective even without registration." 38 Registration of the bank as<br />

mortgagee in the Land Registry gives the borrower's creditors knowledge of the<br />

transaction. Therefore, even if the right is assigned to the SPV but the mortgagee as<br />

named in the Land Registry is still the bank, the mortgage is deemed an unregistered<br />

security interest-which has full force and effect if the borrower becomes insolvent.<br />

The original registration informs third parties of the mortgage. Entries in the Land<br />

Registry are according to parcels and blocks, and the fact that there is now a<br />

different creditor is irrelevant to the fact that a mortgage on the same parcel or block<br />

still exists.<br />

There is similar case law regarding subrogation in favor of a guarantor. A<br />

guarantor that repaid the debt has a right to claim the payment from the principal<br />

debtor, and the security interests that secured the creditor henceforth protect the<br />

guarantor instead. 9 Like Section 5 of the Transfer of Obligations <strong>Law</strong>, Section 12 of<br />

the Guarantee <strong>Law</strong> provides that "the chargor and the creditor shall, at the<br />

guarantor's request, do the acts necessary to make the transfer valid in all respects."" °<br />

In one case it was argued that unless the security interest was not registered to the<br />

guarantor in the appropriate registry, the guarantor had no recourse against the<br />

collateral. 41 The Court ruled that the assignment of the collateral is consistent with<br />

the sense of justice and that such assignment has full force and effect even before it<br />

is reflected in the registry. 42 This decision reflects the policy of recognizing the effect<br />

of the security interest even before it is registered to the new creditor. This<br />

approach, in the Court's view, does not prejudice the rights of the debtor's other<br />

creditors, because even before the assignment they could not collect against the<br />

collateral 3<br />

Similar case law exists regarding security interests. The Pledges <strong>Law</strong> enables<br />

the debtor, or any other person who would be adversely affected by the liquidation<br />

37. See, e.g., CA 1370/01 Kidma Ltd. V. Levy-Tuhrer, Attorneys at <strong>Law</strong>, Isr Dinim DC 32(10) 461;<br />

CC 1256/02 Sharon, Adv. v. Alphasi Shimon, IsrDC 2002(3) 7502. Cf CC (Jer) 2247/03 Reshef v. Levy,<br />

Takdin DC 2004(1) 6761.<br />

38. Pledges <strong>Law</strong> § 4(3).<br />

39. Guarantee <strong>Law</strong>, 5727-1967, 21 ISR 41 (1966-67) (Isr.) §§ 9, 12.<br />

40. Id. § 12.<br />

41. CA 108/59 Pritzker v. Niv. Ltd. (In Liquidation), IsrSC 14, 1545.<br />

42. Id.<br />

43. See, e.g., CA 306/68 The Official Receiver v. Receiver of Palkoltil Ltd., IsrSC 23(1) 256. (holding<br />

that a guarantor that repaid a debt that has priority by law, such as taxes, is entitled to the same priority).<br />

"Actually, what would the debtors be losing if the priority passes from the creditor to the guarantor?<br />

Nothing. The creditors' rights are not violated by the prioritization of a guarantor who paid the debt,<br />

because the debt that he paid had priority over their debts in the first place, and the change in the identity<br />

of the payee has no effect on their interests.").<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 762 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:751<br />

IV.<br />

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS<br />

This paper reviewed the introduction process of securitization to the Israeli<br />

marketplace. This process started in three areas: mortgages, securitization of the<br />

indebtedness in leasing transactions, and securitization of tax money owing to local<br />

government. We focused on the securitization of mortgages and the legal issues<br />

surrounding such transactions.<br />

The popularity of securitization depends on economic factors. A low financial<br />

margin in the mortgage sector would hinder securitization, because it would leave no<br />

profit to be divided between the bank and the SPV. But economic factors are not<br />

the only possible hindrance-judicial uncertainty might also hold back the<br />

development of this market. Since the legislature has not given much thought yet to<br />

this financing instrument, an analysis must be made based on the general provisions<br />

of the law.<br />

In 2005, a government committee examined the local securitization market and<br />

recommended the adoption of a designated statute that would regulate the field.<br />

Such special legislation would answer the main issues reviewed above:<br />

Protection of the debtors whose indebtedness has been securitized. This<br />

protection is particularly important in the mortgage industry. Generally, when<br />

borrowers default on their loans, mortgage banks work out arrangements with the<br />

borrowers-such as debt rescheduling-which help borrowers avoid final breach.<br />

The loan agreement does not oblige the bank to make such concessions, but this is<br />

nevertheless standard practice. Securitization transactions give rise to the concern<br />

that the SPV would not be as considerate to the borrower. The bank intends to stay<br />

in the mortgage industry in the long-term, and looks out for its reputation. The SPV,<br />

on the other hand, is an outsider that has no incentive to make any concessions.<br />

Protection of the borrowers should therefore be regulated by statute.<br />

Clear criteria distinguishing between a true sale and a security interest. A true<br />

sale protects the SPV more effectively, and such protection would incentivize the<br />

securitization market.<br />

The SPV as a secured creditor even though the named mortgagee in the Land<br />

Registry remains the bank. Uncertainty might seriously undermine the securitization<br />

of mortgages because the cost of amending the registration to name the SPV as<br />

mortgagee with regard to all the assigned rights would be very high.<br />

We hope that the committee's recommendations are accepted and that a<br />

comprehensive arrangement regulating the securitization sector passes into law.<br />

Such an arrangement would certainly give this sector a serious boost.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 764 2006-2007


Japan's Personal Insolvency <strong>Law</strong><br />

JUNICHI MATSUSHITA*<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. OVERVIEW OF JAPAN'S PERSONAL INSOLVENCY LAW: BANKRUPTCY<br />

PROCEEDINGS AND SPECIAL REHABILITATION PROCEEDINGS FOR<br />

IND IVID U A L D EBTO RS ....................................................................................... 766<br />

A. Overview of Japan's Personal Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> ........................................ 766<br />

B. Bankruptcy Proceedings of Individual Debtors ....................................... 766<br />

C. Special Civil Rehabilitation Proceedings for Individual Debtors ........... 768<br />

1. O ff icers .................................................................................................. 768<br />

2. C laim V erification Process .................................................................. 768<br />

II.<br />

DEBTORS WITH ABILITY TO REPAY AND POSSIBILITY OF ABUSIVE<br />

F IL IN G S ................................................................................................................. 769<br />

A. Issues Discussed in the Legislative Process ............................................... 769<br />

B. Possibility of A busive Filings ..................................................................... 770<br />

III. C O N C LU SIO N ....................................................................................................... 771<br />

The project involving the comprehensive reform of Japanese insolvency law<br />

started in October 1996, and was finished in November 2004. There are now two<br />

types of judicial proceedings for personal insolvencies under Japanese insolvency<br />

law. The first is straight bankruptcy proceedings based on the Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>, in<br />

which the debtor can be discharged; the other is special civil rehabilitation<br />

proceedings for individual debtors. In Part I of this Article, I offer a brief discussion<br />

of personal insolvency law, as well as bankruptcy proceedings and special civil<br />

rehabilitation proceedings, both for individual debtors. In Part II, I present an<br />

overview of the legislative discussion concerning the treatment of debtors, who<br />

might be able to repay more from future income than that which would be<br />

distributed in bankruptcy proceedings.<br />

Professor at the University of Tokyo, Tokyo, Japan. I would like to express special thanks to<br />

Professor Jay Westbrook for organizing the 13 h Conference of the International Academy of Commercial<br />

and Consumer <strong>Law</strong>. This research was financially supported by the Ministry of Education, Culture, Sports,<br />

Science and Technology (MEXT), Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research on Priority Areas (2), 16090207,<br />

2005.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 765 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:765<br />

I. OVERVIEW OF JAPAN'S PERSONAL INSOLVENCY LAW:<br />

BANKRUPTCY PROCEEDINGS AND SPECIAL REHABILITATION<br />

PROCEEDINGS FOR INDIVIDUAL DEBTORS<br />

A. Overview of Japan's Personal Insolvency <strong>Law</strong><br />

I start by providing a general description of the Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong> and the Civil<br />

Rehabilitation <strong>Law</strong> before focusing on personal insolvency.<br />

The Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong> (Hasan Ho) 1 was comprehensively amended in 2004, and<br />

became effective on January 1, 2005. The Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong> provides for bankruptcy<br />

proceedings, which are applicable to both individuals and legal entities. 2 A<br />

bankruptcy proceeding is a sell-out proceeding where a debtor gives up all assets<br />

(except for those exempt in the case of an individual debtor), the court-appointed<br />

trustee sells these assets, and the proceeds are distributed to creditors on a pro-rata<br />

basis. 3 In 2005, there were 227,053 bankruptcy cases terminated; 216,582 of those<br />

cases involved bankruptcy proceedings of individual debtors.<br />

The Civil Rehabilitation <strong>Law</strong> (Minji Saisei Ho) 4 was enacted in 1999, and<br />

became effective on April 1, 2000. This law provides for civil rehabilitation<br />

proceedings, which are also applicable to both individuals and legal entities. 5 A<br />

rehabilitation proceeding is a pay-out proceeding where a debtor can propose to<br />

keep all assets in exchange for promising to pay off debts from future income over a<br />

period of time according to a rehabilitation plan. 6 A rehabilitation plan becomes<br />

effective upon its acceptance by a majority of unsecured creditors and court<br />

approval. 7 In 2005, there were 27,478 rehabilitation cases terminated; 26,644 of those<br />

cases comprised special rehabilitation proceedings for individual debtors.<br />

B. Bankruptcy Proceedings of Individual Debtors<br />

There are several rules applicable to individual debtors, such as exemption and<br />

discharge. The law provides that exemptions shall include the debtor's household<br />

furnishings, household goods, apparel, household appliances, cash of up to Y990,000, 8<br />

and the debtor's right to receive unpaid salary of up to Y330,000 9 per month. In<br />

addition, the court may, when petitioned by the debtor or at its own discretion,<br />

1. Hasan Ho [Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>], <strong>Law</strong> No. 75 of 2004. The old Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>, <strong>Law</strong> No. 71 of 1922,<br />

was basically modeled upon the old German Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong> of 1877, Konkursordnung. Although many<br />

provisions were amended when the new law was enacted, its basic structure has changed little.<br />

2. Id.<br />

3. Id.<br />

4. Minji Saisei Ho [Civil Rehabilitation <strong>Law</strong>], <strong>Law</strong> No. 225 of 1999. When the Civil Rehabilitation<br />

<strong>Law</strong> became effective, the Composition <strong>Law</strong> (Wagi Ho), which was modeled upon the Austrian<br />

Composition <strong>Law</strong> of 1914, was repealed.<br />

5. Id.<br />

6. Id.<br />

7. Id.<br />

8. Approximately US$8,390 (US$1=¥118). The cap amount was V210,000 before the amendment, and<br />

was raised dramatically-mainly to protect the debtor and dependents thereof.<br />

9. Approximately US$2,797 (US$1=¥118).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 766 2006-2007


2007<br />

JAPAN'S PERSONAL INSOLVENCY LAW<br />

extend the scope of exemption in consideration of certain factors, including the<br />

following: the total amount of other exempted properties, whether the debtor is<br />

employed, and the number and age of family members. Typical examples of<br />

exemption extensions are bank account deposits up to a particular amount, and<br />

ownership of a motor vehicle in cases in which the debtor lives in an area (where the<br />

public transportation system is not well-established or where the debtor runs a<br />

carrier business). There is no homestead exemption in Japan, so the debtor has to<br />

give up real estate.<br />

A filing for a bankruptcy proceeding by the debtor is deemed to be a filing for<br />

discharge. The court grants a debtor a discharge-except in certain instances.<br />

Grounds for denial of discharge include the debtor's wrongdoing in or in connection<br />

with bankruptcy cases-such as concealment of assets to defraud creditors or making<br />

false statements feigning solvency when borrowing money-and refusal of the<br />

debtor to testify or cooperate with the trustee or court.'" The discharge is also<br />

denied if the debtor was granted a discharge in a previous bankruptcy case or<br />

rehabilitation case within certain time limits. Under the old Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>, a<br />

debtor could not receive a discharge in a bankruptcy proceeding if a prior discharge<br />

had been received within ten years of the new filing." It was argued that this period<br />

must be shortened to further protect debtors in the modern economy; although<br />

moral hazards must also be minimized. The new Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong> provides that a<br />

debtor cannot presently receive a discharge if a prior discharge was received within<br />

seven years (rather than ten) of the new filing.' 3 Even in one of the above cases, the<br />

court may grant a discharge at its discretion in consideration of the grounds for<br />

financial failure.14<br />

Under the old Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>, a discharge order did not discharge an<br />

individual debtor from debts for: (1) taxes; (2) compensation for damage caused by<br />

willful tort; (3) wages; or (4) penalties and fines." The new Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>,<br />

however, adds two categories of debts which cannot be discharged: (5) debts for<br />

personal injury or death caused by an intentional or reckless act of the debtor; and<br />

(6) debts to a spouse, former spouse, or child of the debtor, for alimony,<br />

maintenance, or support for the spouse or child 6<br />

In the legislative discussion, it was argued that a cap should apply to debts<br />

under the above categories (5) and (6) to protect the debtor from unlimited<br />

obligations. However, the new Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong> provides for no such limit or cap to<br />

discourage moral hazards.<br />

In practice, most debtors who would satisfy the criteria for the commencement<br />

of bankruptcy proceedings never progress to being formally liquidated because it<br />

appears to creditors that there are no non-exempt assets in the estate with which to<br />

fund the administration of the bankruptcy proceeding, mainly compensation for the<br />

trustee. The Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong> provides that a bankruptcy proceeding be commenced<br />

and then terminated simultaneously (often called "simultaneous termination"), and<br />

10. Hasan Ho [Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>], <strong>Law</strong> No. 75 of 2004.<br />

11. Id.<br />

12. Hasan Ho [Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>], <strong>Law</strong> No. 71 of 1922 (amended 2004).<br />

13. Hasan Ho [Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>], <strong>Law</strong> No. 75 of 2004.<br />

14. Id.<br />

15. Hasan Ho [Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>], <strong>Law</strong> No. 71 of 1922.<br />

16. Hasan Ho [Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong>], <strong>Law</strong> No. 75 of 2004.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 767 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:765<br />

no trustee be appointed." In 2005, of 216,582 bankruptcy cases involving individual<br />

debtors, there were 194,865 simultaneous termination cases (ninety percent). It is<br />

argued that because no investigation by the trustee is conducted in these cases, the<br />

debtor's wrongdoing that might otherwise lead to denial of discharge could be<br />

overlooked and a discharge could be granted. Recently, the court has appointed a<br />

trustee in some consumer bankruptcy cases, and awarded a comparatively lower<br />

amount of compensation to the trustee by limiting the scope of investigation that the<br />

trustee needs to conduct. Most of these cases turn out to be assetless cases, and are<br />

terminated after the trustee's investigation. In 2005, among 216,582 bankruptcy<br />

cases of individual debtors, there were 15,897 cases (seven percent) where trustees<br />

were appointed and terminated because of an assetless estate.<br />

C. Special Civil Rehabilitation Proceedings for Individual Debtors<br />

Because civil rehabilitation proceedings were originally intended mainly for<br />

small- and medium-sized businesses, due to the cost involved, they are rather<br />

burdensome for consumers and individuals who run a business as an individual<br />

proprietorship. In the year 2000, the Civil Rehabilitation <strong>Law</strong> was amended to add<br />

new chapters, one of which specified simplified procedures for individual and<br />

regularly salaried debtors owing ¥50 million or less, with a three-year duration for<br />

the rehabilitation plan in principle. 8 Under special circumstances, the duration of a<br />

plan can be extended to up to five years. 9 Two major features of the simplified<br />

proceedings are as follows:<br />

1. Officers<br />

In most regular civil rehabilitation cases, the court appoints a supervisor, while<br />

debtors continue to have rights to administer and dispose of the debtor's assets,<br />

subject to a broad range of supervision by the supervisor. On the other hand, they<br />

must remain inexpensive and simple, because such proceedings only deal with small<br />

cases. The court may appoint a Rehabilitation Officer for Individuals (Kojin Saisei<br />

Iin), whose function is limited to investigating the debtor's assets and income,<br />

assisting the court in reviewing the legitimacy or amount of claims to which the<br />

debtor or other creditor may object, and advising the debtor in drafting an<br />

appropriate plan.<br />

2. Claim Verification Process<br />

When an objection is raised to a claim filed by the debtor or other creditors, the<br />

court reviews the legitimacy or amount of the claim in summary, rather than plenary,<br />

proceedings. The court makes a binding decision only on the amount of voting<br />

rights for creditors' meetings-allotted to the creditor whose claim is objected toand<br />

there are no provisions for appeal. This decision, however, does not have the<br />

17. Id.<br />

18. Minji Saisei Ho [Civil Rehabilitation <strong>Law</strong>], <strong>Law</strong> No. 225 of 1999.<br />

19. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 768 2006-2007


2007<br />

JAPAN'S PERSONAL INSOLVENCY LAW<br />

same effect as a judgment, in the sense that the decision has no binding effect on the<br />

substance of the claim.<br />

Chapter 13 of the Civil Rehabilitation <strong>Law</strong> provides for two kinds of simplified<br />

Civil Rehabilitation proceedings for individual debtors. 'The first type is for<br />

individual debtors with a generally regular income, and is referred to as "small size<br />

individual rehabilitation." 20 There were 18,567 cases of such proceedings in 2005. In<br />

these proceedings, a rehabilitation plan may become effective with the creditors'<br />

acceptance and the court's confirmation. A plan is accepted if the creditors that<br />

reject the plan in writing are owed half or less of the total allowed claims and<br />

number less than half of all the creditors. This "negative approval standard"<br />

assumes that creditors who do not reject a plan in writing accept the plan. Major<br />

requirements for court confirmation are: (1) a "best interest test," under which each<br />

creditor should receive an amount no less than that which he or she would receive if<br />

the debtor's assets were liquidated under bankruptcy proceedings; and (2) a<br />

minimum payment rate, basically twenty percent, depending on the total amount of<br />

debt. 2 '<br />

The second kind of proceeding is intended for individual debtors with regular<br />

stable income, such as wages, and is called the "wage earners rehabilitation." The<br />

most important feature of such a proceeding is that the rehabilitation plan becomes<br />

effective with the court's confirmation, and without the necessity for creditors'<br />

approval. There were 8,428 cases of such proceedings in 2003, and 8,077 in 2004.<br />

Major requirements for confirmation are not only (1) and (2), as aforementioned,<br />

but also a "disposable income standard," under which the debtor must repay his or<br />

her debts (as modified by a plan) from his or her regular income, less taxes, social<br />

insurance premiums, and permissible living expenses provided by the cabinet order.<br />

II.<br />

DEBTORS WITH ABILITY TO REPAY AND POSSIBILITY OF ABUSIVE<br />

FILINGS<br />

A. Issues Discussed in the Legislative Process<br />

One of the issues most intensively discussed in the legislative process was the<br />

ability of the debtor to opt for bankruptcy proceedings, regardless of the amount of<br />

expected future income. The tentative draft that was publicized for comment in<br />

June 2000 proposed three alternatives: (1) the debtor would be able to choose<br />

between either bankruptcy proceedings or simplified rehabilitation proceedings; (2)<br />

the debtor would be discharged in bankruptcy proceedings only after attempting to<br />

20. Id.<br />

21. The following shows the minimum payment rate or amount based on total amount of debt:<br />

Total Amount of Debts<br />

Minimum Payment Rate/Amount<br />

0 -V1,000,000 100%<br />

¥1,000,000 - ¥5,000,000 V1,000,000<br />

V5,000,000 - V15,000,000 20%<br />

V15,000,000 - V30,000,000<br />

V3,000,000<br />

V30,000,000 - V50,000,000 10%<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 769 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:765<br />

repay his or her debts in rehabilitation proceedings, if his or her expected disposable<br />

income exceeded a certain amount; and (3) the debtor would be discharged in<br />

bankruptcy proceedings only once he or she had repaid his or her debts to the<br />

amount receivable by each creditor if the debtor chose simplified rehabilitation<br />

proceedings (where the "minimum payment rate standard" or "disposable income<br />

standard" would apply), if the expected disposable income of the debtor exceeded a<br />

certain amount.<br />

As long as a debtor chooses a rehabilitation proceeding, creditors will be able<br />

to receive an amount no less than what they would receive if the debtor's assets were<br />

liquidated under bankruptcy proceedings, because a "best interest test" applies when<br />

a rehabilitation plan is confirmed. On the other hand, if a debtor with the ability to<br />

repay more than hypothetical bankruptcy distribution chooses a bankruptcy<br />

proceeding and is discharged, it could be argued that the interest of creditors is<br />

damaged in the sense that they lost an opportunity to be repaid from the debtor's<br />

future income. This concern is serious when a debtor has minimum assets to<br />

maintain his or her life now but where high and regular future income is definitely<br />

expected.<br />

An argument for the second and third alternatives is that creditors-namely<br />

consumer financing and credit card companies -usually look to debtors' future<br />

income rather than, or at least in addition to, debtors' current assets. Under the<br />

second and third alternatives, debtors would be forced, directly or indirectly, to pay<br />

more than what would be distributed in bankruptcy proceedings.<br />

The Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong> Committee finally chose the first alternative, mainly<br />

because both the second and third were rather impractical. Calculating the expected<br />

disposable income means having to initially estimate the debtor's income in the near<br />

future, and then deducting tax, social insurance, and necessary expenses of the<br />

debtor and dependents, which may vary based on the number and age of<br />

dependents. Calculation would have to be done by neutral court-appointed officers,<br />

and hearings of debtors would also be necessary. Although there is no empirical<br />

study on the ability of debtors who filed for bankruptcy proceedings to repay, it is<br />

said that only a small portion of debtors would be able to repay more from their<br />

future income. Calculating the expected disposable income to pick up debtors with<br />

the ability to repay more in all personal bankruptcy cases,2 numbering as many as<br />

two hundred thousand, would be time-consuming and not at all cost-effective. This<br />

gate-keeping difficulty was critical in making the decision. Therefore, under the<br />

current law, a debtor can choose between either bankruptcy proceedings or<br />

rehabilitation proceedings, regardless of the amount of expected disposable income.<br />

B. Possibility of Abusive Filings<br />

Some practitioners argue that current laws allow petitions for bankruptcy<br />

proceedings to be dismissed through abusive use (general clause in Japanese law), if<br />

the amount of the expected disposable income of the debtor is relatively high. As<br />

far as I know, however, there has been no reported case in which a petition for a<br />

22. One of the related issues is whether calculating the expected disposable income is required for all<br />

personal bankruptcy cases or only in cases where creditors request it. Under the latter scheme, the<br />

required cost would be less, but there is a concern that a particular type of creditors would request it<br />

abusively.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 770 2006-2007


2007<br />

JAPAN'S PERSONAL INSOLVENCY LAW<br />

bankruptcy proceeding was dismissed because of the amount of the debtor's<br />

disposable income. It is pointed out that an argument for dismissal based on abusive<br />

filing is problematic because there are no clear criteria for judging whether a certain<br />

filing is an abuse and judgments could vary from judge to judge. 23<br />

Should Japanese insolvency laws be amended in the future to introduce a new<br />

legal scheme to prevent abusive filings? In order to answer this difficult question, I<br />

first focus on who will bear the burden of defaults in a legal scheme to prevent<br />

abusive filings. On the one hand, under current law, the cost of defaults of<br />

individual debtors could be passed along to other persons who borrow money from<br />

consumer financing companies (some of which are financially related to mega<br />

banks), in the form of higher interest rates; 24 the cost could even be passed on to all<br />

other people, in the form of higher interest rates and higher prices. On the other<br />

hand, if the second or third of the aforementioned alternatives (Part I.A) is<br />

introduced, the cost of gate-keeping in bankruptcy or rehabilitation proceedings<br />

would be a burden to courts, and ultimately to all tax payers. It would also cause a<br />

delay in insolvency proceedings and other regular civil cases. It could be argued that<br />

a solution to the cost problem is a legal scheme under which gate-keeping- that is,<br />

calculation of debtors' future income-is needed only in cases in which one or more<br />

creditors request it, and the cost for gate-keeping is borne by the creditors who<br />

requested it. But this idea cannot be an answer, because those creditors can easily<br />

pass along the cost they paid to the court to other people in the form of higher<br />

interest rates and higher prices.<br />

Should the view that a legal scheme is needed to prevent abusive filings prevail,<br />

it should first be discussed whether it can be justified to help creditors (mainly<br />

consumer financing companies and credit card companies) in collecting their loans,<br />

by establishing a threshold to sort out debtors and by imposing costs to apply the<br />

court system to all taxpayers. Would this be cost effective? Even if it were, could we<br />

call it justice?<br />

III. CONCLUSION<br />

The consumer credit industry has developed dramatically for several decades,<br />

and it has both a bright and dark side. To enjoy the bright side of consumer credit,<br />

we need to pay the cost that inevitably accompanies its development. When we<br />

design a legal scheme for personal insolvency, we must decide how to allocate the<br />

cost and whether it can be justified from the viewpoint of justice. I hope this paper<br />

interests commercial lawyers and consumer lawyers worldwide.<br />

23. There was a judge who rendered many decisions to deny discharge, most of which were reversed<br />

in appellate courts. Although these are exceptional and extreme cases, bankruptcy attorneys are<br />

concerned about arbitrary decisions.<br />

24. In this context, it is interesting that there was recently a legislative discussion to lower interest rate<br />

caps from 29% a year to 15-20% a year.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 771 2006-2007


HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 772 2006-2007


The Landmark 2005 Hague Convention on<br />

Choice of Court Agreements<br />

VED P. NANDA*<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. INT R O D U CTIO N ................................................................................................... 774<br />

II. SCOPE OF THE CONVENTION .............................................................................. 777<br />

III. JU R ISD ICT IO N ...................................................................................................... 780<br />

IV. RECOGNITION AND ENFORCEMENT ................................................................. 782<br />

V . SELECTE D ISSU ES ................................................................................................ 783<br />

A. Preliminary Questions and Intellectual Property Rights ......................... 783<br />

B . Transition P rovisions .................................................................................. 784<br />

C. Contracts of Insurance and Reinsurance ................................................... 784<br />

D. Relationship with Other International Instruments .................................. 785<br />

VI. IMPLEMENTATION OF THE CONVENTION IN THE UNITED STATES ................ 786<br />

VII. APPRAISAL AND RECOMMENDATION .............................................................. 787<br />

Vice Provost, Evans University Professor, Thompson G. Marsh Professor of <strong>Law</strong>, and Director,<br />

International Legal Studies Program, University of Denver Sturm College of <strong>Law</strong>. This is an expanded<br />

version of the author's presentation on August 11, 2006, at the <strong>13th</strong> <strong>Biennial</strong> Conference of the<br />

International Academy of Commercial and Consumer <strong>Law</strong>, University of Texas School of <strong>Law</strong>, Austin,<br />

August 9-12, 2006.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 773 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:773<br />

I. INTRODUCTION<br />

The Convention on Choice of Court Agreements,' adopted at the twentieth<br />

session of the Hague Conference on Private International <strong>Law</strong> on June 30, 2005, is<br />

an important step toward international harmonization of national conflicts rules on<br />

forum selection clauses. The Convention both strives to ensure the recognition and<br />

enforcement of international choice of court clauses in the context of international<br />

business by providing uniform rules, and validates the parties' choice of forum as the<br />

single basis for jurisdiction. At the same time, it provides sufficient safeguards for<br />

governmental interests and for rendering and enforcing courts.<br />

It is worth recalling that the United <strong>State</strong>s Supreme Court had validated party<br />

autonomy as early as 1972 in MIS Bremen v. Zapata Off-Shore Co., 2 by giving effect<br />

to "the legitimate expectations of the parties, manifested in their freely negotiated<br />

agreement, by specifically enforcing the forum clause." 3 By eliminating uncertainties<br />

regarding the place of suit by forum selection in advance, such contractual<br />

stipulations were found by the Court to constitute an "indispensable element in<br />

international trade, commerce, and contracting."'<br />

The Court approved of what it called a recent trend in adopting "a more<br />

hospitable attitude" toward choice of forum clauses, and called upon federal district<br />

courts sitting in admiralty to follow this as "the correct doctrine." 5 The Court<br />

established a reasonableness test to determine the validity of forum selection<br />

clauses, as it held that "such clauses are prima facie valid and should be enforced<br />

unless enforcement is shown by the resisting party to be 'unreasonable' under the<br />

circumstances." 6 A strong showing could indeed be made for setting aside the forum<br />

selection clauses "for such reasons as fraud or overreaching" or if the enforcement<br />

would be "unreasonable and unjust" or contrary to "a strong public policy of the<br />

forum."' The Bremen Court's reasoning that "[w]e cannot have trade and commerce<br />

in world markets and international waters exclusively on our terms, governed by our<br />

laws, and resolved in our courts,"" would certainly apply equally in every other<br />

country.<br />

1. See Convention on Choice of Court Agreements, June 30, 2005, reprinted in 44 I.L.M. 1294 (2005),<br />

available at http://www.hcch.net/index-en.php?act=conventions.pdf&cid=98 [hereinafter Hague<br />

Convention]; see generally, e.g., SAMUEL P. BAUMGARTNER, THE PROPOSED HAGUE CONVENTION ON<br />

JURISDICTION AND FOREIGN JUDGMENTS, (2003); see also Ronald A. Brand, Introductory Note to the 2005<br />

Hague Convention on Choice of Court Agreements, 44 I.L.M. 1291 (2005); Trevor C. Hartley, The Hague<br />

Choice-of-Court Convention, 31 EUR. L. REV. 414 (2006); Thalia Kruger, The 20th Session of the Hague<br />

Conference: A New Choice of Court Convention and the Issue of EC Membership, 55 INT'L & COMP. L.Q.<br />

447 (2006); Andrea Schulz, The Hague Convention of 30 June 2005 on Choice of Court Agreements, 2 J.<br />

PRIVATE INT'L L. 243 (2006); Louise Ellen Teitz, The Hague Choice of Court Convention: Validating Party<br />

Autonomy and Providing an Alternative to Arbitration, 53 AM. J. COMP. L. 543 (2005); Peter D. Trooboff,<br />

International <strong>Law</strong>: Foreign Judgment, NAT'L L.J., Oct. 17, 2005, at 13, available at<br />

http://www.hcch.net/upload/bibl37-pt.pdf.<br />

2. MIS Bremen v. Zapata Off-Shore Co., 407 U.S. 1 (1972).<br />

3. Id. at 12.<br />

4. Id. at 13-14.<br />

5. Id. at 10.<br />

6. Id. at 10.<br />

7. Id. at 15.<br />

8. Bremen, 407 U.S. at 9.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 774 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE LANDMARK 2005 HAGUE CONVENTION<br />

Bremen was a case in admiralty; although both federal and state courts have<br />

generally followed the Bremen holding in non-admiralty cases as well. However,<br />

were the U.S. to become a contracting party to the Choice of Court Convention, the<br />

Convention may have impact, not only on cases in U.S. courts involving<br />

international forum selection clauses, but eventually even in the domestic setting as<br />

jurisdictional law may be harmonized by federal legislation. 9<br />

Although the Hague Convention was adopted in June 2005, the actual drafting<br />

of the document began at the Hague Conference in 1992 with the United <strong>State</strong>s'<br />

initiative to create a global convention on jurisdiction and the recognition and<br />

enforcement of judgments in civil and commercial matters.' 0 The United <strong>State</strong>s'<br />

interest in such a convention is driven by the obvious need it perceives for a legal<br />

structure to "support the growth of global markets" and promote international<br />

cooperation." Moreover, since the United <strong>State</strong>s is not a party to any treatybilateral<br />

or multilateral-on recognition and enforcement of foreign judgments, the<br />

U.S. finds itself at a major disadvantage, for re-litigation becomes a prerequisite for<br />

the enforcement of U.S. judgments abroad. The U.S. courts are perceived to be<br />

more hospitable to the enforcement of foreign judgments than foreign courts are to<br />

U.S. judgments. 2<br />

The negotiation process was lengthy and cumbersome. A Preliminary Draft<br />

Convention on Jurisdiction and Foreign Judgments in Civil and Commercial Matters<br />

was finally adopted at the October 1999 meeting of the Hague Conference, 3 which<br />

generally mirrored in its structure and content the prior European Union<br />

instruments on the topic-the Brussels Convention of September 27, 1968," and the<br />

9. See Kevin M. Clermont & Kuo-Chang Huang, Converting the Draft Hague Treaty into Domestic<br />

Jurisdictional <strong>Law</strong>, in A GLOBAL LAW OF JURISDICTION AND JUDGMENTS: LESSONS FROM THE HAGUE<br />

191, 192-93 (John J. Barcelo, III & Kevin M. Clermont eds., 2002) (advocating federal legislation<br />

standardizing jurisdictional rules for state and federal courts).<br />

10. See Peter H. Pfund, The Project of the Hague Conference on Private International <strong>Law</strong> to Prepare<br />

a Convention on Jurisdiction and the Recognition/Enforcement of Judgments in Civil and Commercial<br />

Matters, 24 BROOK. J. INT'L L. 7, 8 (1998).<br />

11. See Letter from Jeffrey D. Kovar, U.S. Dept. of <strong>State</strong>, Assistant Legal Advisor for Private Int'l<br />

<strong>Law</strong>, to J.H.A. van Loon, Sec'y Gen., Hague Conference on Private Int'l <strong>Law</strong> 2 (Feb. 22, 2000), available at<br />

http://www.cptech.org/ecom/hague/kovar2loon22022000.pdf.<br />

12. See, e.g., Kevin M. Clermont, Jurisdictional Salvation and the Hague Treaty, 85 CORNELL L. REV.<br />

89, 89 (1999) (stating "the United <strong>State</strong>s eagerly gives appropriate respect to foreign judgments, despite<br />

sometimes getting no respect in return"); see also Peter D. Trooboff, Ten (and Probably More) Difficulties<br />

in Negotiating a Worldwide Convention on International Jurisdiction and Enforcement of Judgments: Some<br />

Initial Lessons, in A GLOBAL LAW OF JURISDICTION AND JUDGMENTS: LESSONS FROM THE HAGUE 263,<br />

263 (John J. Barcelo, III & Kevin M. Clermont eds., 2002); Stephen B. Burbank, The Reluctant Partner:<br />

Making Procedural <strong>Law</strong> for International Civil Litigation, 57 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 103, 138-39 (1994)<br />

(stating "[tihe problem with unilateral generosity is that it may weaken U.S. bargaining power when, other<br />

countries having chosen not to follow our example, it attempts to work out mutually acceptable<br />

agreements. That looms as a difficulty for the United <strong>State</strong>s in pursuing a multilateral convention on the<br />

recognition and enforcement of foreign judgments") (footnotes omitted).<br />

13. See Report on the Preliminary Draft Convention on Jurisdiction and Foreign Judgments in Civil<br />

and Commercial Matters, drawn up by Peter Nygh & Fausto Pocar, Preliminary Document No. 11 of<br />

August 2000, available at http://www.hcch.net/upload/wop/jdgmpdll.pdf.<br />

14. See Convention of 27 September 1968 on Jurisdiction and the Enforcement of Judgments in Civil<br />

and Commercial Matters, 1968, 1990 O.J. (C 189) 2; see also Council Regulation (EC) No. 44/2001 of 22<br />

December 2000 on Jurisdiction and the Recognition and Enforcement of Judgments in Civil and<br />

Commercial Matters, 2001 O.J. (L 12) 1 (supplanting the 1968 Brussels Convention on March 1, 2002)<br />

[hereinafter Brussels Convention 2000].<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 775 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:773<br />

Lugano Convention of September 16, 1988." Subsequent consultations showed<br />

serious differences among the delegates on the text of this ambitious project, parts of<br />

which had been adopted by narrow majorities and, consequently, would not have<br />

received wide approval.<br />

A lack of consensus on the text was coupled with the concern that in the era of<br />

special issues raised by e-commerce and intellectual property rights, the rules based<br />

on the Brussels and Lugano conventions, adopted so long ago, would not meet<br />

contemporary needs. Thus, formal negotiations on the 1999 draft were suspended. 16<br />

Subsequent informal discussions between 2000 and 2002 led to the realization that a<br />

consensus could not be reached on a global convention of such a wide scope as<br />

envisaged earlier; the decision was made to scale down the project and use a<br />

"bottom-up-approach," starting with choice of court clauses on business-to-business<br />

cases, on which there already was broad agreement. 7 After several sessions of an<br />

informal working group during 2002-2003, the group prepared a draft that it<br />

submitted to the Commission on General Affairs and Policy of the Hague<br />

Conference in April 2003. The Commission met in December 2003 and April 2004<br />

and produced a Preliminary Draft Convention, and, after further deliberations and<br />

work, a diplomatic session convened in June 2005 unanimously adopting the<br />

Convention. 8<br />

Three basic rules that ensure the effectiveness of the Hague Convention form<br />

its core. First, the court specified by an exclusive and valid choice of court<br />

agreement must hear the case.' 9 Second, pursuant to limited exceptions, all other<br />

courts must suspend or dismiss the case. 2 ' Third, the resulting judgment of the<br />

chosen court must generally be enforced by courts in other Contracting <strong>State</strong>s. 2 ' In<br />

addition to these three rules, the Convention contains a fourth optional rule on<br />

reciprocal declarations, that Contracting <strong>State</strong>s may declare that they will recognize<br />

and enforce judgments of other Contracting <strong>State</strong>s resulting from non-exclusive<br />

choice of court agreements. These provisions will be elaborated later.<br />

15. See Convention of 16 September 1988 on Jurisdiction and the Enforcement of Judgments in Civil<br />

and Commercial Matters, 1988 O.J. (L 319) 9.<br />

16. See Schulz, supra note 1, at 244-48 (detailing the negotiations). As First Secretary at the<br />

Permanent Bureau of the Hague Conference on Private International <strong>Law</strong>, Schulz was in charge of the<br />

negotiations beginning in 2002.<br />

17. Id.<br />

18. See Preliminary Documents to Convention of 30 June 2005 on Choice of Court Agreements,<br />

available at http://www.hcch.net/index-en.php?act=conventions.publications&dtid=35&cid=98 (pertaining<br />

to the Convention and providing pertinent details regarding the process leading to its adoption); e.g., The<br />

Impact of the Internet on the Judgments Project: Thoughts for the Future, Preliminary Document No. 17<br />

of Feb. 2002; Choice of Court Agreements in International Litigation: Their Use and Legal Problems to<br />

Which They Give Rise in the Context of the Interim Text, Preliminary Document No. 18 of Feb. 2002;<br />

Report on the Work of the Informal Working Group on the Judgments Project, In Particular on The<br />

Preliminary Text Achieved at Its Third <strong>Meeting</strong> March 2003, Preliminary Document No. 22 of June 2003;<br />

Draft Report on the Preliminary Draft Convention on Exclusive Choice of Court Agreements, Drawn up<br />

by Trevor C. Hartley & Masato Dogauchi, Preliminary Document No. 26 of Dec. 2004; Comments on the<br />

Preliminary Draft Convention on Exclusive Choice of Court Agreements, Preliminary Document No. 29 of<br />

May 2005; The Future Convention on Exclusive Choice of Court Agreements and Arbitration, Preliminary<br />

Document No. 32 of Jun. 2005.<br />

19. Hague Convention, supra note 1, art. 5.<br />

20. Id. art. 6.<br />

21. Id. art. 8.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 776 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE LANDMARK 2005 HAGUE CONVENTION<br />

This discussion will begin in the next section on the scope of the Convention.<br />

The third section will review the jurisdictional issues, which will then lead to a<br />

section on recognition and enforcement. Selected issues will be discussed next, and<br />

issues related to the Convention's implementation in the United <strong>State</strong>s will be<br />

reviewed after that. The final section will cover an appraisal of the Convention.<br />

II.<br />

SCOPE OF THE CONVENTION<br />

Article 1 defines the Convention's scope. It applies only to international cases,<br />

only if there is an exclusive choice of court agreement, and only in civil and<br />

commercial matters. The definition of "international" varies between the<br />

Convention's application regarding jurisdiction and its application regarding<br />

recognition and enforcement. A case is international unless the parties are residing<br />

in the same Contracting <strong>State</strong> and all relevant elements except the location of the<br />

chosen court are connected only with that <strong>State</strong>. Thus, merely the choice of a<br />

foreign court in an otherwise totally internal case does not make it international.<br />

The Convention's reach is expansive, however, for the purpose of recognition<br />

and enforcement, as the mere fact that a judgment is given by a foreign court suffices<br />

to make it international. To illustrate: assume that the parties, both residents of<br />

France, a Contracting <strong>State</strong>, enter into an exclusive forum selection agreement,<br />

choosing the courts in Italy to resolve their disputes and that all elements relevant to<br />

the dispute are connected with France. For jurisdictional purposes, this is not an<br />

international case. If a court in Italy, however, renders judgment, and the judgment<br />

is taken by one of the parties to Germany or France (assuming that France, Italy,<br />

and Germany are all Contracting <strong>State</strong>s), both Germany and France will be<br />

obligated to recognize and enforce the judgment. Recognizing this anomalous<br />

situation, the Convention does authorize the <strong>State</strong>, namely France in this example,<br />

to declare that it will not recognize or enforce such judgments. 22<br />

The Convention defines an entity or person other than a natural person is as a<br />

resident of a state-where it has its statutory seat, central administration, or<br />

principal place of business, or the <strong>State</strong> under whose law it was formed or<br />

incorporated. 3 A judgment under the Convention follows the traditional meaning of<br />

"judgment" for recognition purposes-namely that it is given by a court on the<br />

merits and does not include interim measures of protection, 24 which are not covered<br />

under the Convention.2<br />

To provide further clarity, the Convention explicitly states that it does not<br />

govern interim measures of protection and that it "neither requires nor precludes the<br />

grant, refusal or termination of interim measures of protection by a court of a<br />

Contracting <strong>State</strong> and does not affect whether or not a party may request or a court<br />

should grant, refuse or terminate such measures. 2 6<br />

The Convention uses the term "<strong>State</strong>" or "Contracting <strong>State</strong>" to include states<br />

with two or more territorial units with different legal systems, such as Canada, the<br />

22. Id. art. 20.<br />

23. Id. art. 4(2).<br />

24. Id. art. 4(l).<br />

25. Hague Convention, supra note 1. art. 7.<br />

26. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 777 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:773<br />

United Kingdom, and the United <strong>State</strong>s, as well as "Regional Economic Integration<br />

Organizations," such as the European Union. 27 As to the former, the Convention<br />

provides that the term "<strong>State</strong>" or "Contracting <strong>State</strong>" applies, where appropriate, to<br />

"the relevant territorial unit," that is, either the larger entity (say the United<br />

Kingdom), or its sub-unit (say Scotland). 28 Thus, the choice of a Scottish court would<br />

mean that Scotland would be the "Contracting <strong>State</strong>.<br />

As to the Regional Economic Integration Organizations, the Convention<br />

authorizes such an entity to become a party to the Convention if the organization's<br />

member states have granted it "competence over some or all of the matters<br />

governed by [the] Convention." 3 Such an organization may also declare that it<br />

alone and not its member states individually will be party to the Convention but that<br />

they will also be bound by virtue of the organization's adherence. 3 "<br />

An exclusive choice of court agreement is defined as an agreement that "must<br />

be concluded or documented (i) in writing; or (ii) by any other means of<br />

communication which renders information accessible so as to be usable for<br />

subsequent reference." 32 Accompanying this rather limited form requirement is the<br />

provision that the agreement designate "the courts of one Contracting <strong>State</strong> or one<br />

or more specific courts of one Contracting <strong>State</strong> to the exclusion of the jurisdiction<br />

of any other courts" to resolve past and future disputes. 3 Assuming that the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s ratifies the Convention to apply federally as well as to all its states, an<br />

agreement could, for example, specify the federal courts of the United <strong>State</strong>s, or the<br />

Federal District Court of Colorado, or the state courts of Colorado.<br />

The Convention validates party autonomy, presuming exclusivity for a choice of<br />

court agreement "unless the parties have expressly provided otherwise." 34 Thus, an<br />

agreement designating the courts of a non-Contracting <strong>State</strong> is excluded from the<br />

Convention's coverage. Finally, the Convention provides severability of a choice of<br />

court agreement from the rest of a contract so that the validity of the exclusive<br />

forum selection clause "cannot be contested solely on the ground that the contract is<br />

not valid." 35<br />

The Convention appropriately confines its scope to exclusive choice of court<br />

agreements, although it does provide for reciprocal declarations by Contracting<br />

<strong>State</strong>s that their courts will recognize and enforce judgments of other Contracting<br />

<strong>State</strong>s resulting from non-exclusive choice of court agreements. 36 Otherwise, it<br />

27. Id. art. 25.<br />

28. Id.<br />

29. Id.<br />

30. Id. art. 29.<br />

31. Hague Convention, supra note 1, art. 30.<br />

32. Id. art. 3(c); see also Schulz, supra note 1, at 248 (explaining that article 3(c)(ii) of the Hague<br />

Convention is drawn from the UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong> on Electronic Commerce); c.f, Convention on the<br />

Recognition and Enforcement of Foreign Arbitral Awards art. Il(1), June 10, 1958, 21 U.S.T. 2517, 330<br />

U.N.T.S. 38 (providing a contrast to the flexible language of The Hague Convention art. 3 with the rigid<br />

requirement in the 1958 Convention that the "agreement [be] in writing under which the parties undertake<br />

to submit to arbitration all or any differences" between them regarding "a defined legal relationship,<br />

whether contractual or not, concerning a subject matter capable of settlement by arbitration") [hereinafter<br />

New York Convention].<br />

33. Hague Convention, supra note 1, art. 3(a).<br />

34. Id. art. 3(b).<br />

35. Id. art. 3(d).<br />

36. Id. art. 22.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 778 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE LANDMARK 2005 HAGUE CONVENTION<br />

would have to address the issue of parallel proceedings and consequently the rigid<br />

rule of priority, which is the practice in Europe, but on which there is no wide<br />

consensus. The United <strong>State</strong>s, for example, rejects the priority concept and instead<br />

follows the forum non conveniens approach; thus, the United <strong>State</strong>s courts routinely<br />

apply public and private law factors in exercise of their broad discretion to<br />

determine whether they should or should not hear the case.<br />

The presumption of exclusivity resolves an issue fraught with difficulty in the<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s courts, where generally forum selection clauses are not presumed to<br />

be exclusive absent explicit language to that effect. Furthermore, courts in the<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s differ on what makes a forum selection clause mandatory and hence<br />

enforceable, or permissive and hence discretionary. A Tenth Circuit case decided in<br />

2002, K & V Scientific Co., Inc. v. BMW, aptly makes the point: "Mandatory forum<br />

selection clauses contain clear language showing that jurisdiction is appropriate only<br />

in the designated forum. 37 In contrast, permissive forum selection clauses authorize<br />

jurisdiction in a designated forum, but do not prohibit litigation elsewhere." 8 The<br />

clause in question read: "[j]urisdiction for all and any disputes arising out of or in<br />

connection with this agreement is Munich. All and any disputes arising out of or in<br />

connection with this agreement are subject to the laws of the Federal Republic of<br />

Germany." 3 9 The Tenth Circuit's conclusion was that "is Munich" does not<br />

sufficiently imply "is [only] Munich." 4<br />

The court added that "where venue is specified [in a forum selection clause]<br />

with mandatory or obligatory language, the clause will be enforced; where only<br />

jurisdiction is specified [in a forum selection clause], the clause will generally not be<br />

enforced unless there is some further language indicating the parties' intent to make<br />

venue exclusive.'<br />

Among the U.S. circuit courts, the Second, Fifth, Seventh, Ninth, and Eleventh<br />

Circuits have also held such clauses to be permissive, while the Sixth Circuit has<br />

concluded otherwise.<br />

Regarding the third limit on the Convention's scope-that it applies only in<br />

civil or commercial matters-the rapporteurs note that the use of both terms was<br />

necessary because in some legal systems "civil" and "commercial" are considered<br />

separate and mutually exclusive categories. 42 However, as will be discussed next,<br />

several issues normally considered to fall within the civil and commercial categories<br />

are excluded from the scope of the Convention.<br />

In addition to the exclusion of forum selection clauses in consumer and<br />

employment contracts, which obviously do not belong in a convention aimed at<br />

promoting "international trade and investment, ' 43 article 2 enumerates sixteen<br />

subject matters for exclusion." Several of these excluded matters are of special<br />

governmental interests or are subject to regional or international treaties or national<br />

37. K&V Scientific Co., Inc. v. BMW, 314 F.3d 494 (10th Cir. 2002).<br />

38. Id. at 498 (internal quotations omitted).<br />

39. Id. at 496.<br />

40. Id. at 498-501.<br />

41. Id. at 499 (citations omitted).<br />

42. Hague Convention, supra note 1, art. 1.<br />

43. Id. pmbl., art. 2.<br />

44. See id. arts. 2(2)(a)-(p).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 779 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:773<br />

rules. 45 These include the status and legal capacity of natural persons and family law<br />

and succession matters." Other excluded matters include insolvency, the carriage of<br />

passengers and goods, marine pollution, anti-trust (competition) matters, torts, rights<br />

in rem in immovable property, the validity of intellectual property rights other than<br />

copyrights and related rights, limited proceedings regarding infringement of<br />

intellectual property rights, and the validity of entries in public registers." However,<br />

the scope of the Convention does include proceedings where one of the excluded<br />

matters "arises merely as a preliminary question and not as an object of the<br />

proceedings." 8<br />

Also specifically excluded are arbitration and related proceedings. 9 Specifically<br />

not excluded are proceedings involving a government, a government agency, or any<br />

person acting on behalf of a government. 0 The Convention does not "affect<br />

privileges and immunities of <strong>State</strong>s or of international organisations." 51<br />

Also, a <strong>State</strong> is authorized to declare that it will not apply the Convention to a<br />

specific matter in which it has a strong interest. 2 However, the Convention does<br />

provide adequate safeguards: first, it requires the <strong>State</strong> making such a declaration to<br />

define it "clearly and precisely" in order to ensure that the declaration is "no<br />

broader than necessary; , 5 1 second, the <strong>State</strong> is to notify the Depositary (the<br />

government of the Netherlands) which will inform the other <strong>State</strong>s; 4 third, such a<br />

declaration will not take effect for at least three months if the Convention is already<br />

in force for the <strong>State</strong> making it; 5 fourth, it will not apply to contracts concluded<br />

before the Convention takes effect; 56 and fifth, acknowledging reciprocity, the<br />

Convention provides that where the chosen court is in the <strong>State</strong> making the<br />

declaration, other <strong>State</strong>s are not required to apply the Convention regarding the<br />

matter in question. 7 III. JURISDICTION<br />

Articles 5 and 6 prescribe jurisdictional rules. Under article 5, the designated<br />

court of a state must decide the case "unless the agreement is null and void under<br />

the law of that state , ''5 which includes its choice of law under its conflict of laws<br />

rules. This provision will have a considerable impact in the United <strong>State</strong>s because<br />

once the Convention is ratified, the United <strong>State</strong>s courts will no longer be able to use<br />

the familiar doctrine of forum non conveniens, under which they currently have the<br />

discretion to dismiss the proceedings in favor of another court.<br />

45. See Schulz, supra note 1, at 247; see also Brand, supra note 1 at 1292.<br />

46. Hague Convention, supra note 1, arts. 2(a), 2(2)(b)-(d).<br />

47. Id. arts. 2(2)(e)-(p).<br />

48. Id. art. 2(3).<br />

49. Id. art. 2(4).<br />

50. Id. art. 2(5).<br />

51. Id. art. 2(6).<br />

52. Hague Convention, supra note 1, art. 21(1).<br />

53. Id. art. 21(1).<br />

54. Id. arts. 32, 33.<br />

55. Id. art. 32(4).<br />

56. Id. art. 32(5).<br />

57. Id. art. 21(2)(b).<br />

58. Hague Convention, supra note 1, art. 5(1).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 780 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE LANDMARK 2005 HAGUE CONVENTION<br />

However, under article 19, the freedom to do so is partly restored as a <strong>State</strong><br />

may declare that its courts, if chosen in an exclusive choice of court agreement, may<br />

refuse to "determine disputes" if there is no other connection with that <strong>State</strong> except<br />

the location of the chosen court." After having made a declaration under article 19,<br />

a <strong>State</strong> may conceivably mandate its courts to refuse jurisdiction under these<br />

circumstances. Similarly, the doctrine of lis pendens, familiar on the European<br />

scene, will not apply because the designated court cannot refuse to hear the case<br />

under the rationale that another court was seised first.<br />

60<br />

Rules on subject matter and venue remain unaffected under this provision.<br />

Thus, the choice of court agreement has no effect if the chosen court lacks the<br />

subject matter or if the venue is improper. The chosen court of a Contracting <strong>State</strong><br />

may transfer the case to another court in that <strong>State</strong> under its law. 6 ' As an example,<br />

such a chosen court may be federal courts in the United <strong>State</strong>s or the Federal<br />

District Court of Colorado. In either case, the chosen court is authorized to transfer<br />

the case according to U.S. law. 62 Similarly, the Convention provides that a court with<br />

the discretion to transfer should give due consideration to the choice of the parties. 63<br />

Article 6 requires the court that is seised, but not located, in the state of the<br />

chosen court to suspend or dismiss proceedings unless one of the followings<br />

exceptions applies: 64 The agreement is "null and void" under the law of the chosen<br />

court; the capacity is lacking under the law of the court seised; giving effect to the<br />

agreement would lead to "manifest injustice" or be "manifestly contrary to public<br />

policy" of the court seised; the agreement cannot reasonably be performed because<br />

of exceptional circumstances beyond the control of the parties; or the chosen court<br />

has decided not to hear the case. 63 This rule will also apply where the chosen court<br />

transfers the case to another court in the same state as permitted under the<br />

Convention. 6 '<br />

Pursuant to the "null and void" exception as noted above in connection with<br />

article 6, the Convention prescribes that the choice of court agreement's substantive<br />

validity must be examined under the law of the chosen court, including the choice of<br />

law rules of the state of the chosen court, as the Convention does not prescribe its<br />

own independent rule on substantive validity. 67<br />

59. Id. art. 19.<br />

60. Id. art. 5(3).<br />

61. Id. art. 5(3)(b)<br />

62. See 28 U.S.C. § 1404 (stating that a federal district court may, for the convenience of the parties<br />

and in the interest of justice, transfer any civil action to any other district or division where it might have<br />

been brought).<br />

63. Id. art. 5(3)(b).<br />

64. See Hague Convention, supra note 1 art. 6(a)-(e).<br />

65. Id.; c.f, New York Convention, supra note 32, art. 11(3) (providing for similar exceptions as those<br />

found in article 6, except that the Hague Convention provides that the court seised may hear the case (but<br />

it is not obligated to do so) if the chosen court has decided not to hear the case).<br />

66. See Schulz, supra note 1, at 253.<br />

67. Hague Convention, supra note 1, art. 6(a).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 781 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:773<br />

IV.<br />

RECOGNITION AND ENFORCEMENT<br />

Article 8 requires the recognition and enforcement of the judgment of a chosen<br />

court in other Contracting <strong>State</strong>s.' No review of the judgment on merits is allowed<br />

by the court addressed, which is bound by the court of origin's findings of fact unless<br />

it is a default judgment. 69 Also, the status of the judgment in the court of originwhether<br />

it has effect and whether it is enforceable-determines whether it will be<br />

recognized or enforced. 7 ° Similarly, if the judgment is under review in the state of<br />

origin or if the time limit for seeking review there has not expired, the addressed<br />

<strong>State</strong> may postpone or refuse recognition or enforcement."<br />

Article 9 enumerates exceptions when recognition or enforcement may be<br />

refused. 2 Several of these are similar to those contained in Article 6 on jurisdiction,<br />

such as when the agreement is "null and void"; capacity of a party to the agreement<br />

is lacking under the law of the requested <strong>State</strong>; and "enforcement would be<br />

manifestly incompatible" with the public policy of the requested <strong>State</strong>. 73 Other<br />

exceptions include fraud in obtaining the judgment, and defective service. 7 " As to<br />

inconsistent judgments between the same parties, the mere fact that the inconsistent<br />

judgment is from the requested <strong>State</strong> suffices as an exception. 75 If, however, the<br />

inconsistent judgment is from another <strong>State</strong>, the Convention requires that it must be<br />

earlier, involve the same cause of action, and fulfill the conditions needed for its<br />

recognition in the requested <strong>State</strong>.<br />

Article 11 states another exception. Judgments awarding damages, including<br />

exemplary or punitive damages, may be refused to the extent that they "do not<br />

compensate a party for actual loss or harm suffered. 7 The court is to "take into<br />

account whether and to what extent the damages awarded by the court of origin<br />

serve to cover costs and expenses relating to the proceedings. 78<br />

As mentioned earlier, a <strong>State</strong> may declare under article 20 that if the parties'<br />

residence, their relationships, and all other elements relevant to the dispute except<br />

the location of the chosen court, are connected only with the requested <strong>State</strong>, its<br />

courts will refuse to recognize or enforce a judgment of a court of another<br />

Contracting <strong>State</strong>. 7 9<br />

68. See id. art. 8(1); see also id. art. 8(5) (including judgments pursuant to transferred cases except that<br />

"where the chosen court had discretion as to whether to transfer the case to another court, recognition or<br />

enforcement of the judgment may be refused against a party who objected to the transfer in a timely<br />

manner in the <strong>State</strong> of origin").<br />

69. Id. art. 8(2).<br />

70. Id. art. 8(3).<br />

71. Id. art. 8(4).<br />

72. Hague Convention, supra note 1, arts. 9(a)-(g).<br />

73. Id. arts. 9(a), (b), (e).<br />

74. Id. arts. 9(c), (d).<br />

75. Id. art. 9(f).<br />

76. Id. art. 9(g).<br />

77. Id. art. 11(1).<br />

78. Hague Convention, supra note 1, art. 11(2).<br />

79. Id. art. 20.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 782 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE LANDMARK 2005 HAGUE CONVENTION<br />

V. SELECTED ISSUES<br />

A. Preliminary Questions and Intellectual Property Rights<br />

Articles 2(3) and 10 address the treatment of preliminary questions. If<br />

excludable subject matter arises under article 2(2), or is excludable pursuant to an<br />

article 21 declaration, and the subject matter is not an object of the proceedings but<br />

is merely a preliminary question, those "proceedings are not excluded from the<br />

scope of [the] Convention. ' "" Furthermore, if the excluded matter is not an object of<br />

the proceedings but arises by way of defense, such proceedings are not excluded<br />

from the Convention. 8 ' For example, in a dispute between a licensor and a licensee<br />

on an alleged breach of contract regarding royalties due to the licensor, the licensee<br />

should not escape the application of the Convention to the contract by raising the<br />

defense of the alleged invalidity of the intellectual property right.<br />

Article 10, in conjunction with the excluded matters, provides that the<br />

preliminary ruling given by the court in the example above on the validity of the<br />

intellectual property right "shall not be recognized or enforced under [the]<br />

Convention" in other Contracting <strong>State</strong>s. 82 This is an issue the court might have had<br />

to decide, for the obligation to pay royalties might have depended on the validity of<br />

the intellectual property right. Paragraphs 2 and 4 provide that recognition or<br />

enforcement of the judgment, as for example to pay the licensor, "may be refused if,<br />

and to the extent that, the judgment was based on a [preliminary] ruling on [an<br />

excluded] matter." 83 '<br />

Article 10(3) adds that the recognition or enforcement authorized under 10(2)<br />

and 10(4) (for payment of royalties in the example used above regarding the dispute<br />

between the licensor and the licensee) may be refused only where the ruling on<br />

which the judgment was based, namely the validity of the intellectual property rights<br />

(other than a copyright or a related right), is inconsistent with the judgment or<br />

decision of the competent authority in the requested <strong>State</strong> or another <strong>State</strong> where<br />

that intellectual property right is granted 4 This means that the judgment may be<br />

refused only if the <strong>State</strong> where the intellectual property right is granted finds the<br />

purported right to be invalid. 8 "<br />

Moreover, the decision on recognition and enforcement of the judgment<br />

mentioned above may be postponed if at the time of request for such recognition or<br />

enforcement, proceedings on the validity of the intellectual property right in<br />

question are still pending in the <strong>State</strong> that granted the right. 86<br />

As noted, the Convention provides a balanced approach to the extremely<br />

sensitive issues of intellectual property rights respecting <strong>State</strong> sovereignty while<br />

rejecting party autonomy to determine the validity of most intellectual property<br />

rights. The compromise reached, which seems to have satisfied the intellectual<br />

80. Id. arts. 2(3), 10(1).<br />

81. Id. art. 2(3).<br />

82. Id. art. 10(1).<br />

83. Id. arts. 10(2), (4).<br />

84. Hague Convention, supra note 1, art. 10(3).<br />

85. Id. art. 10(3)(a).<br />

86. Id. art. 10(3)(b).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 783 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:773<br />

property community, excludes the validity of intellectual property rights from its<br />

coverage with the exception of copyright and related rights."' Accordingly, the<br />

Convention does not apply to infringement of these excluded rights unless<br />

infringement proceedings are brought or could have been brought for breach of a<br />

contract between the parties related to such rights."<br />

B. Transitional Provisions<br />

To meet the parties' expectations and to validate party autonomy, the<br />

Convention states transitional provisions. 9 First, the Convention does not apply if it<br />

is not in force for the <strong>State</strong> of the chosen court under the exclusive choice of court<br />

agreement when the agreement is concluded. 9 In other words, parties may not avail<br />

themselves to the benefits of the Convention through choice of court agreements if<br />

the Convention is not yet in force in the chosen jurisdiction. Conversely, if the<br />

Convention is in force in the chosen jurisdiction, the chosen court must hear the<br />

case, all other courts must decline jurisdiction, and all other Contracting <strong>State</strong>s must<br />

recognize and enforce the judgment of the chosen court. 9<br />

Second, if the Convention is not yet in force in the <strong>State</strong> of the chosen court,<br />

the Convention does not apply to proceedings that take place there. 92 Accordingly,<br />

any court requested to recognize and enforce the judgment of the chosen court is not<br />

obliged to do so under article 8." Nor is the court seised on the merits required to<br />

dismiss the case as required under Article 6 of the Convention. 9'<br />

These provisions, however, do not apply to non-exclusive choice of court<br />

agreements authorized under article 22. These reciprocal declarations by<br />

Contracting <strong>State</strong>s allow that their courts will recognize and enforce judgments of<br />

other Contracting <strong>State</strong>s resulting from non-exclusive choice of court agreements.<br />

<strong>State</strong>s may set specific time limits in such declarations pertaining to the application<br />

of the Convention.<br />

C. Contracts of Insurance and Reinsurance<br />

Article 17 will be most helpful to the insurance industry. Under its provisions,<br />

proceedings under a contract of insurance (or reinsurance) fall within the scope of<br />

the Convention and are not excluded on the ground that such a contract relates to a<br />

matter to which the Convention is inapplicable. 95 For example, although marine<br />

pollution is excluded from the Convention's coverage under Article 2(2)(g), a<br />

contract of insurance for marine pollution falls within the Convention's coverage.<br />

Assuming that marine pollution has occurred and the insured brings a case against<br />

87. Id. art. 2(2)(n).<br />

88. Id. art. 2(2)(o).<br />

89. See id. art. 16.<br />

90. Hague Convention, supra note 1, art. 16.<br />

91. Id. arts. 5,6.8, 16(1).<br />

92. Id. art. 16(2).<br />

93. See id. art. 8(1).<br />

94. Id. art. 16(2).<br />

95. Id. art. 17(1).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 784 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE LANDMARK 2005 HAGUE CONVENTION<br />

the insurer under an exclusive choice of court agreement for refusing her<br />

indemnification, the Convention allows the suit.<br />

Assume further that the insured secures a judgment on her suit. Recognition<br />

and enforcement of that judgment may not be limited or refused on the ground that<br />

the contract includes liability indemnification of the insured or reinsured regarding<br />

an excluded matter or an award of damages to which Article 11 on noncompensatory<br />

damages might apply.<br />

D. Relationship with other International Instruments<br />

Article 26 provides rules regarding the relationship of the Hague Convention to<br />

other treaties or instruments. 96 First, the Convention aims at reaching compatibility<br />

with other treaties. 97 It also does not affect the application of the rules of a regional<br />

arrangement that is a party to the Convention. 8 However, the issue of<br />

incompatibility could arise when the Hague Convention and the Brussels I<br />

Regulation, would both apply. The Convention would claim exclusive jurisdiction of<br />

the chosen court and the latter Brussels I Regulation would prescribe a rigid rule of<br />

priority of the seised court and the recognition and enforcement of a judgment given<br />

by the court of a Member <strong>State</strong> in all others without examining the jurisdictional<br />

basis of the first court. Under Article 23 of the Brussels I Regulation, the<br />

Regulation would apply if one of the parties is domiciled in an E.C. Member <strong>State</strong>.<br />

However, under Article 26(6) of the Hague Convention, in such a situation the<br />

Hague Convention will apply, while the Brussels I Regulation will apply where none<br />

of the parties is resident in a Contracting <strong>State</strong> that is not an E.C. Member <strong>State</strong>. As<br />

to the recognition and enforcement of judgments, the Brussels I Regulation will<br />

apply where both the court granting the judgment and the one in which enforcement<br />

is sought are located in the E.C.<br />

The Hague Convention generally follows the 1969 Vienna Convention's<br />

framework which prescribes rules of international law pertaining to treaties. 99<br />

Specifically, Article 30(2) of the Vienna Convention approaches the problem of<br />

inconsistency and incompatibility between treaties by providing that, "when a treaty<br />

specifies that it is subject to, or that it is not to be considered as incompatible with,<br />

an earlier or later treaty, the provisions of that other treaty prevail."''<br />

Under a provision of Article 26, when a Contracting <strong>State</strong> is a party to a treaty<br />

and all the parties are residents in Contracting <strong>State</strong>s which are all parties to that<br />

treaty, the treaty applies." 1 Moreover, states that are party to the Hague Convention<br />

as well as prior instruments, are authorized to comply with their previous obligations<br />

to any non-Contracting <strong>State</strong>.' 0 ' The prior treaty may continue to apply with the<br />

provision that recognition or enforcement may not be granted "to a lesser extent<br />

96. Hague Convention, supra note 1, art. 26.<br />

97. Id. art. 26(1).<br />

98. Id. art. 26(6).<br />

99. United Nations Convention on the <strong>Law</strong> of Treaties, opened for signature May 23 1969, entered into<br />

force Jan. 27, 1980. 1155 U.N.T.S. 331, reprinted in 8 I.L.M. 679 (1969).<br />

100. Id. art. 30(2).<br />

101. Hague Convention, supra note 1, art. 26(2).<br />

102. Id. art. 26(3).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 785 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:773<br />

than under [the Hague] Convention." ' 3 Treaties on specific subject matters,<br />

whether concluded before or after the Hague Convention, may also apply, provided<br />

that "the Contracting <strong>State</strong> has made a declaration" to that effect.' °<br />

VI. IMPLEMENTATION OF THE CONVENTION IN THE UNITED STATES<br />

Assuming that implementing legislation will be required in the United <strong>State</strong>s, '<br />

Professor Curtis Reitz has advocated implementation through the uniform state law<br />

process rather than federal legislation, on the rationale that uniform state legislation<br />

appropriately harmonizes treaty provisions with pertinent state law.' °6 In response,<br />

Professor Stephen Burbank first analyzes the restrictive powers of the federal<br />

government and the states regarding the issues addressed in the Hague Convention<br />

and second, discusses and evaluates the "considerations that bear on the wise use of<br />

these powers."'" 7 He notes Congressional enactment of federal legislation for the<br />

New York Convention for Arbitral Agreements and Arbitral Awards as well as<br />

Congressional ratification of the Hague Service Convention and the Hague<br />

Evidence Convention after the Congressional determination that a federal response<br />

was necessary to address the problems of international litigation.' He adds: "[T]he<br />

interests of US participants in the global marketplace would be well served by<br />

uniform international standards for the recognition and enforcement of US<br />

judgments in other nations and of foreign-country<br />

9<br />

judgments in the United <strong>State</strong>s."'<br />

Professor Burbank identifies the issues on which the Hague Convention<br />

provides for disuniformity: 1) the law governing the validity of contract; 2) the law<br />

governing the capacity to enter into contract; 3) public policy norms; and 4)<br />

procedures regarding service of process and of "procedural fairness" that are<br />

considered fundamental."' He then provides cogent arguments in favor of uniform<br />

federal norms rather than state legislation."' On "public policy" he appropriately<br />

refers to the American <strong>Law</strong> Institute's Project on Recognition and Enforcement of<br />

Foreign Judgments: Analysis and Proposed Federal Statute. 2 as proposing a model<br />

statute that points to state law in some situations:<br />

(a) A foreign judgment shall not be recognized or enforced in a court in<br />

the United <strong>State</strong>s if the party resisting recognition or enforcement<br />

establishes that: ... (vi) the judgment or the claim on which the judgment<br />

is based is repugnant to the public policy of the United <strong>State</strong>s, or to the<br />

103. Id. art. 26(4).<br />

104. Id. art. 26(5).<br />

105. See Stephen B. Burbank, Federalism and Private International <strong>Law</strong>: Implementing the Hague<br />

Choice of Court Convention in the United <strong>State</strong>s, 2 J. PRIVATE INT'L L. 287, 289-292 (2006) (discussing<br />

whether implementing legislation in the United <strong>State</strong>s is necessary or appropriate).<br />

106. Curtis R. Reitz, Globalization, International Legal Developments, and Uniform <strong>State</strong> <strong>Law</strong>s, 51<br />

LOYOLA L. REV. 301, 319-27 (2005).<br />

107. Burbank, supra note 105, at 293-308.<br />

108. Id. at 296-97.<br />

109. Id. at 297.<br />

110. Id. at 300-01.<br />

111. Id. at 301-07.<br />

112. PROJECT ON RECOGNITION AND ENFORCEMENT OF FOREIGN JUDGMENTS: ANALYSIS AND<br />

PROPOSED FEDERAL STATUTE (Proposed Final Draft 2005).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 786 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE LANDMARK 2005 HAGUE CONVENTION<br />

public policy of a particular state of the United <strong>State</strong>s when the relevant<br />

legal interest, right, or policy is regulated by state law." 3<br />

Similarly, he prefers federal determination rather than state-by-state decisions<br />

regarding partial declarations on jurisdiction and enforcement as authorized in<br />

articles 19 and 20 as discussed earlier.' I concur with his conclusion that based on<br />

the need for certainty, efficiency, and uniformity, "federal implementation through<br />

legislation prescribing federal law that is mostly uniform, but a few provisions of<br />

which may borrow designated state law, would impose lower transaction and<br />

administrability costs, with no loss of accessibility, than would state<br />

'<br />

implementation.<br />

VII. APPRAISAL AND RECOMMENDATION<br />

The presumption of exclusivity established in the Hague Choice of Court<br />

Convention is of special significance in the United <strong>State</strong>s. The major reason is that<br />

notwithstanding the U.S. Supreme Court's ruling in Bremen in 1972, which validates<br />

forum selection clauses, U.S. courts have not generally held forum selection clauses<br />

to be exclusive without explicit language showing that jurisdiction is exclusively in<br />

the designated forum." 6<br />

Thus, following the ratification and implementation of the Hague Convention<br />

in the United <strong>State</strong>s, there should be no uncertainty that choice of court agreements<br />

will be held exclusive by U.S. courts. As the existing uncertainty on this issue is<br />

removed and there is predictability that a decision by the chosen U.S. court will be<br />

recognized and enforced abroad, a foreign business should find no disincentive in<br />

choosing a U.S. court as a forum to resolve potential disputes in business-to-business<br />

transactions.<br />

The importance of the Hague Convention is not limited just to the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s, for it is widely seen as a viable alternative to the 1958 New York Convention<br />

on the Recognition and Enforcement of Foreign Arbitral Awards, under whose<br />

provisions not only arbitration awards but arbitration clauses are recognized and<br />

enforced abroad." 7 However, the Hague Convention should not be seen as<br />

competing with the New York Convention, as evidenced by the International<br />

Chamber of Commerce (ICC) and its International Court of Arbitration's strong<br />

support for this new development.<br />

The Hague Convention has gained wide support. For instance, the intellectual<br />

property community considers the Convention to be an important instrument, as it<br />

will make licensing agreements easier to enforce." 9 Similarly, the Convention will be<br />

113. Id. § 5(a)(vi), cited at Burbank, supra note 105, at 307.<br />

114. See Burbank, supra note 105, at 309.<br />

115. Id.<br />

116. See supra notes 37-41 and accompanying text.<br />

117. See New York Convention, supra note 32, art. 11(3) (obligating courts of Contracting <strong>State</strong>s to<br />

enforce arbitration agreements as well as arbitration awards).<br />

118. See Schulz, supra note 1, at 266.<br />

119. See Hartley, supra note 1, at 424.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 787 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:773<br />

equally important for the insurance industry.' The legal profession has also<br />

enthusiastically endorsed it: professional associations, including the American Bar<br />

Association, the International Bar Association, the International <strong>Law</strong> Association,<br />

and the American Society of International <strong>Law</strong>, have all featured the Convention at<br />

their conferences.' The ABA's Section of International <strong>Law</strong> stated in its August<br />

2006 report:<br />

The Choice of Court Convention addresses a specific perceived need for<br />

facilitating global transactions and providing certainty for US parties and<br />

litigants. It can be understood as a contract drafting tool and should be<br />

part of cross-border planning starting today. The Convention is also a<br />

means of dispute resolution, providing a viable alternative to arbitration.<br />

122<br />

It recommended that the ABA urge the U.S. government "promptly to sign,<br />

ratify and implement the Hague Convention on Choice of Court Agreements. '' 123 At<br />

its annual meeting the ABA resolved to make that recommendation.' It is in the<br />

interest of the United <strong>State</strong>s to ratify the Convention and implement it through<br />

federal legislation.<br />

120. See id.; see also Schulz, supra note 1, at 260-61.<br />

121. See Schulz, supra note 1, at 266 and n.65.<br />

122. American Bar Association, Recommendation, Adopted by the House of Delegates Aug. 7-8,<br />

2006, available at http://www.abanet.org/intlaw/policy/investment/hcca0806.pdf.<br />

123. The author was in attendance for these proceedings.<br />

124. American Bar Association, Recommendation, supra note 122.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 788 2006-2007


Banking <strong>Law</strong> Reform and Users-Consumers in<br />

Developing Economies: Creating an<br />

Accessible and Equitable Consumer Base from<br />

the "Excluded"<br />

JOSEPH J. NORTON*<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. INTRO D U CTIO N ................................................................................................... 790<br />

II.<br />

EVALUATING BANKING SECTOR LEGAL REFORM FOR DEVELOPING<br />

COUNTRIES: THE PAST FIFTEEN YEARS ........................................................... 792<br />

A. Modern Banking Sector Legal Reform as G7/G8 Mandated and as<br />

P art of N IFA ................................................................................................ 792<br />

B. NIFA and the Role of International Standards: An Industrialized<br />

C ountry Initiative ........................................................................................ 795<br />

III.<br />

WORLD BANK'S NEW AGENDA ON FINANCIAL ACCESS AND EQUITY<br />

ISSU E S ................................................................................................................... 7 98<br />

A . The C ountry Studies .................................................................................... 800<br />

B. FSAPs: One Possible Supporting Pillar for the "Next Generation" of<br />

Financial Sector Legal Reform .................................................................. 804<br />

IV.<br />

Two CURRENT DEVELOPMENTS OF SIGNIFICANCE: MICROFINANCING<br />

AND PRIVATE INDUSTRY PARTICIPATION ....................................................... 806<br />

A . M icrofinancing ............................................................................................ 806<br />

1. B ackground ............................................................<br />

807<br />

2. Im provem ent of M icrofinance ............................................................ 807<br />

3. The R egulatory R eform ...................................................................... 809<br />

B. An Example of Non-Regulatory Public-Private Initiative: The Case<br />

of South A frica ............................................................................................ 810<br />

1. B ackground ........................................................................................... 811<br />

* SJD (Mich.), Dipl. (Hague), DPhil. (Oxon), LLD (Lond), LLD (hc;Stockh). James L. Walsh<br />

Distinguished Faculty Fellow and Professor in Financial Institutions <strong>Law</strong> at the SMU Dedman School of<br />

<strong>Law</strong>, Dallas, Texas; formerly the Sir John Lubbock Professor of Banking <strong>Law</strong>, University of London<br />

(1993-2005). This article is derived from a presentation prepared for the <strong>13th</strong> <strong>Biennial</strong> Conference for the<br />

International Academy of Commercial and Consumer <strong>Law</strong>, August 9-12, 2006, Austin, Texas and from<br />

work on an internal study for the World Bank.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 789 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

2. Responding to the Challenge: The Financial Sector Charter .......... 811<br />

3. Im plem entation M echanism s .............................................................. 812<br />

V. CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS: THE NEED FOR A SUITABLE LEGAL-<br />

INSTITUTIONAL INFRASTRUCTURE AND POLICY REORIENTATION .............. 814<br />

I. INTRODUCTION<br />

The subject-matter of this article was originally conceived of as consumer<br />

protection issues in banking sectors of developing countries. In first approaching<br />

this topic area, the author had on his "industrialized country hat" which<br />

automatically assumes that there preexists a broad consumer base from which to<br />

work. But in stepping back and putting on his "developing country legal reform<br />

hat," the author came to realize that approximately two-thirds of the world's people<br />

are effectively excluded from the mainstream banking and financial sectors of their<br />

respective countries, thus denying them an ability to meet basic financial needs and<br />

any realistic prospects of wealth creation, and foregoing the mainstream financial<br />

systems in these countries from more fully maturing in the sense of contributing<br />

more fully to the developmental needs of these countries. As such, what consumer<br />

base would exist in a developing country would only encapsulate the top of the<br />

socioeconomic pyramid of that country. Thus, the critical, foundational issue that<br />

needs to be addressed respecting consumer banking issues in developing countries is<br />

that of "inclusion."<br />

The primary proposition being set forth in this article is that, notwithstanding<br />

the plethora of global banking sector reform over the past two decades, the equitable<br />

and accessible provision of banking services has never been a core component of<br />

modern banking sector legal reform and assessment in the developing world. As<br />

such, before one can sensibly talk about a viable banking and financial sector<br />

framework in a developing country, a reasonably broad user (i.e., consumer) base<br />

needs to be developed. In effect, the banking and financial system of the developing<br />

country needs to become accessible to the "excluded": serving just the top of the<br />

economic pyramid is shortsighted and, in the long term, counterproductive. Once a<br />

broad and equitable base is established, a developing country can sensibly and<br />

effectively address the formulation of an adequate consumer protection framework<br />

so that new entrants and those still remaining outside the mainstream financial<br />

sector are not discriminated against or treated unfairly. While these conclusions<br />

seem to be obvious, it is only most recently that the International Financial<br />

Institutions (IFIs), particularly the World Bank, have begun to more systematically<br />

address these fundamental deficiencies in developmental legal reform agendas<br />

respecting the banking/financial sector.'<br />

1. Certain abbreviations and acronyms used in this article include: anti-money laundering (AML);<br />

Basel Committee on Banking Supervision; Bank for International Settlements (BIS); World Bank's<br />

Country Assistance Strategies (CAS); Consultative Group to Assist the Poor (CGAP); counterterrorism<br />

financing; European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD); European Union; Financial<br />

Action Task Force; Financial Sector Assessment (FSA); Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP);<br />

Financial Stability Forum (FSF); Group of 7 (G7); Group of Eight (G8); Group of Ten (G10); Group of<br />

Twenty (G20); General Agreement on Trade in Services; International Association of Deposit Insurers<br />

(IADI); International Association of Insurance Supervisors (IAIS); International Accounting Standards<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 790 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 791<br />

From this author's perspective of over two decades of study and practical<br />

involvement with financial sector reform in developing, transitioning, and emerging<br />

economies, he is of the considered view that: (i) the modern banking and financial<br />

sector law reform policies and infrastructures process is of relatively recent vintage;<br />

(ii) this reform process has been largely crisis-oriented and reactive by necessity and<br />

has become driven largely by industrialized countries' systemic objectives of<br />

preventing financial crises and related contagion, fostering global financial stability,<br />

and more recently, maintaining financial sector integrity; and (iii) this "first<br />

generation" of reform has never had the luxury of being clearly thought through in<br />

terms of how developmental factors such as access, equality, and user protection can<br />

be incorporated into the overall financial sector legal reform processes in an<br />

integrated and coherent manner that promotes the United Nations' Millennium<br />

Development Goal of alleviating poverty. 2<br />

It is the general view of this author that the future banking and financial sector<br />

legal policy and infrastructure reform process of the IFIs and others in the economic<br />

development arena should systematically and thoughtfully undertake this reform<br />

process within, or alongside of, a complementary framework and context of<br />

meaningful and relevant economic-social development policy objectives, including<br />

the object of making the financial base broader and more inclusionary. Quite<br />

simply, such reform should be coordinated on the policy, implementation, and<br />

assessment levels, with the broader economic development objectives and policies of<br />

the particular developing country.<br />

Part II of this article will attempt to evaluate banking sector legal reform efforts<br />

as to developing countries over the past decade and a half. Part III will consider<br />

recent selective efforts of the World Bank in addressing the access and equity issues<br />

respecting the banking sector. Part IV will consider two current developments of<br />

relevance: the rise of microfinancing and the efforts to engage private industry's<br />

cooperative efforts. Part V will provide some concluding reflections on the<br />

importance of the legal infrastructural, institutional, and policy reorientation<br />

dimensions of such reform efforts.<br />

Committee (IASC); International Federation of Accountants; International Financial Arrangement (IFA);<br />

International Finance Corporation (IFC); International Financial Institution (IFI); International Monetary<br />

Fund (IMF); International Organization of Securities Commissions (IOSCO); Joint Forum (JF); Legal<br />

Vice Presidency of the World Bank (LVP); Microfinance Institutions (MFI); New International Financial<br />

Architecture (NIFA): Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD); Regional<br />

Financial Institution (RFI); Reports on the Observance on Standards and Codes (ROSC); Small and<br />

Medium-sized Enterprises (SME); International Bank for Reconstruction and Development and the<br />

International Development Association (WB, or World Bank); and World Trade Organization (WTO).<br />

2. See generally U.N. Millennium Development Goals, available at<br />

http://www.unmillenniumproject.org.<br />

3. As will be pointed out throughout this paper, modern "financial sector development" is not<br />

necessarily consistent with or supportive of what should be a developing country's broader "economic<br />

development" planning and policies. But cf., Thorsten Beck, Ash Demirguc-Kunt and Maria Soledad<br />

Martinez Peria, Reaching Out: Access To and Use of Banking Services Across Countries (World Bank<br />

Policy Research Working Paper No. 3754, Oct. 2005).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 791 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

II.<br />

EVALUATING BANKING SECTOR LEGAL REFORM FOR<br />

DEVELOPING COUNTRIES: THE PAST FIFTEEN YEARS<br />

Banking sector legal reform as a mandate for domestic and international<br />

financial authorities of developing countries is clearly of recent vintage, and is<br />

largely the reactive byproduct of the major industrialized countries' concern over<br />

financial crises and the quest for global financial stability during the 1990s,' the new<br />

transitioning economies arising from the collapse of the Soviet Union, the<br />

enlargement of the European Union, and the ongoing onslaught of economic<br />

globalization -each of which are interconnected in various ways. 5 More specifically,<br />

this reform over the past decade has been largely driven by the G7/G8 grouping of<br />

industrialized countries.<br />

A. Modern Banking Sector Legal Reform as G7/G8 Mandated and as Part of NIFA<br />

In terms of becoming a major concern of the IFIs, banking sector, and other<br />

financial sectors, legal reform as to developing countries began gaining credence and<br />

taking shape as part of the G7/G8 6 invention of the notion of a New International<br />

Financial Architecture. NIFA in fact is a misnomer of sorts and in some sense a<br />

public relations ploy to dress over an ongoing quandary of what to do with an<br />

international financial "non-system." 8 Yet, even if no true "architecture" had<br />

existed to be replaced by NIFA, and though NIFA is itself probably not a true<br />

architecture or system, a working base did come to exist through the NIFA, from<br />

which a new architecture and a next generation of banking and financial sector legal<br />

reform could be developed.<br />

4. In fact, when one reviews the annual intergovernmental Communiques of the G7/G8 from 1975<br />

through the mid-1990s, one notes, by conspicuous absence, that the financial sector infrastructure<br />

(including its legal dimensions) is left unattended. Globally significant macroeconomic issues were the rule<br />

of the day for the annual agendas.<br />

5. It is true one can find specific anecdotal examples of financial law-related reforms during the 1960s<br />

and 1970s, but these were largely isolated reforms designed to facilitate a certain development project. An<br />

IFI-related example was in the early years of the EBRD, which views itself more as an International<br />

Finance Corporation-type of commercially oriented development institution: in the 1990s any institutional<br />

or legal reform in its mandate countries was specifically project-focused. It was only by the mid-1990s, that<br />

the EBRD set up a law reform component of its General Counsel's Office, but the component tended to<br />

look at more generic law reform issues, such as a model secured transaction law. See, e.g., EMERGING<br />

FINANCIAL MARKETS AND SECURED TRANSACrIONS (Joseph J. Norton & Mads Andenas eds., 1998).<br />

6. Inaugurated in 1975 by the then-heads of the French and German governments for the purpose of<br />

creating a more meaningful forum for Heads of <strong>State</strong> Summits of the major industrialized countries, the<br />

G8 (known as the G7 from 1976 until 1998, when Russia was fully admitted) has met annually to consider<br />

the major global macroeconomic and political issues. See the major G8 Information Centre website<br />

maintained by the University of Toronto, available at http://www.g7.utoronto.ca.<br />

7. The first use of the specific term "New International Financial Architecture" is often attributed to<br />

Mr. Michel Camdessus, former Managing Director of the IMF, who began regularly to use this term in<br />

1998. E.g., Michel Camdessus, Toward a New Financial Architecture for a Globalized World, Address at<br />

the Royal Institute of International Affairs (May 8, 1998), available at<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/1998/O50898.htm); J. J. Norton, A 'New International Financial<br />

Architecture'?: Reflections on the Possible <strong>Law</strong>-Based Dimensions, in A NEW INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL<br />

ARCHITECTURE: A VIABLE APPROACH 135-182 (J.B. Attanasio & J.J. Norton eds., 2002).<br />

8. Norton, supra note 7, at 180-82.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 792 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 793<br />

NIFA, as it has unfolded through the various G7/G8 annual summits over the<br />

past decade, has endeavoured to coordinate and direct a wide grouping of different,<br />

though related, international bodies that have their own mandates, jurisdictions, and<br />

powers: (i) multilateral agencies (IMF, WB, BIS, OECD); 9 (ii) policy formulation<br />

groups (G7/G8, G10, G20);' and (iii) international regulatory and standard-setting<br />

authorities and arrangements (IFAs) (Basel Committee, IAIS, IOSCO, IASC, JF,<br />

FSF)." In addition, in various and increasing ways, NIFA has brought the private<br />

financial industry sectors into the equation. 2 As such, NIFA might be viewed as an<br />

evolving policy construct moving towards a new governance structure which reflects<br />

a public-private partnership among governments, financial sector authorities,<br />

international financial institutions, and private international financial institutions in<br />

the search of a stable, viable global financial environment. However, the main focus<br />

of this "public-private partnership" is, for the most part, on global financial stability<br />

issues and on deepening financial markets rather than on broadening such markets<br />

in terms of greater financial inclusion or serving the socioeconomic development<br />

needs of the majority of the population of developing countries. 3<br />

At its 1994 Naples Summit, the G7 Heads of <strong>State</strong> made financial sector reform<br />

issues a major agenda item for its 1995 Halifax Summit. 4 But it was really not until<br />

the Birmingham (1998), Cologne (1999), and Okinawa (2000) Summits that the<br />

NIFA began to be fleshed out. 15 The G7 Finance Minister Reports in Cologne (June<br />

1999) and Okinawa (June 2000) specifically followed up, in some detail, on the<br />

following NIFA components:<br />

- Strengthened Macroeconomic Policy for Emerging Economies;<br />

- Strengthened and Reformed IFIs;<br />

- Accurate and Timely Informational Flows and Transparency;<br />

- Strong Financial Regulation in Industrial Countries;<br />

- Strong Financial Systems in Emerging Markets;<br />

- Exchange Rate Policies;<br />

- Sound Accounting Standards;<br />

- Legal Infrastructure;<br />

9. See, e.g., Andrew Sheng, The New International Financial Architecture: Is There a Workable<br />

Solution?, in A NEW INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL ARCHITECTURE: A VIABLE APPROACH, supra note 7,<br />

ch. 1.<br />

10. See IMF, A Guide to Committees, Groups, and Clubs (2006), available at<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/groups.htm..<br />

11. See generally GEORGE ALEXANDER WALKER, INTERNATIONAL BANKING REGULATION LAW<br />

POLICY AND PRACTICE (2001); JOSEPH JUDE NORTON, DEVISING INTERNATIONAL BANK SUPERVISORY<br />

STANDARDS (1995).<br />

12. Virtually all of the international bodies involved directly or indirectly included the financial<br />

industry sectors (as they are direct subjects of such standards) in their devising, revising, and implementing<br />

of international financial sector standards.<br />

13. See, e.g., Joseph J. Norton, A Perceived Trend in Modern International Financial Regulation:<br />

Increasing Reliance on a Public-Private Partnership, 37 INT'L L. 43 (2003).<br />

14. See Group of Seven [G7], Naples Summit Communique (July 9, 1994), available at<br />

http://www.g7.utoronto.ca/summit/1994naples/communique/introduction.html.<br />

15. See generally Heads of <strong>State</strong> and Related Communiqubs from the Various Summits from 1975-<br />

2006, available at http://www.g7.utoronto.ca/summit.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 793 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

- Corporate Governance;<br />

- Anticorruption/Money Laundering;<br />

- Technological Innovation/Adaptation; and<br />

- Risk Management.' 6<br />

An integral element of all this would be a significant law-based dimension<br />

evolving around global principles and standards setting (codes) as to the following: 7<br />

- Banking Regulation;<br />

- Capital Markets Regulation;<br />

- Insurance Supervision;<br />

- Corporate Governance;<br />

- Financial Conglomerates;<br />

- Payment, Settlement and Custody Mechanisms;<br />

- Pension Funds and Collective Investment Schemes; and<br />

- Accounting and Auditing Standards.<br />

Though the G7 singled out treatment of emerging economies as to financial<br />

sector reforms, the bottom line appears to be that these economies needed to adopt<br />

and implement the unfolding "international standards and best practices," with the<br />

IFIs playing a major role (directly and indirectly) in the implementation,<br />

transmission, and related technical assistance processes. Otherwise, the focus of the<br />

G8 heads of state and finance ministers at Birmingham, Cologne, and Okinawa as to<br />

developing countries was mainly on debt alleviation for the poorest of the<br />

developing countries and on integration of the developing world into the "global<br />

environment."'" The underlying assumption appears to be that sustained global<br />

growth, increased trade, and investment liberalization will bring increased economic<br />

growth for developing countries and that a strengthened international financial<br />

system will foster such global growth. 9<br />

From 2000 to the present, the G8 appears to have been consumed with a<br />

proliferation of international political and security crises. As to financial sector<br />

reform, the use of Financial Sector Assessment Programs and greater IFI<br />

cooperation is encouraged, and there is increased concern as to financial crimes,<br />

corruption, and fighting terrorism financing. 2° Debt relief for the poorest countries<br />

gained traction with the 2005 Gleneagles Summit. 2 '<br />

16. See infra notes 20-22 and acccompanying text.<br />

17. The FSF oversees these standards and codes and has compiled the series of key standards and<br />

codes into a working Compendium. See FSF, Compendium of Standards, available at<br />

http://www.fsforum.org/compendium/about.html.<br />

18. See, e.g., G7 Finance Ministers, Cologne, Germany, June 18-20, 1999, Report of the Koln<br />

Economic Summit, available at http://www.g8.utoronto.ca/finance/fm06l999.htm.<br />

19. Id.<br />

20. See, e.g., G7 Finance Ministers, Fukuoka, Japan, July 8, 2000, Report<br />

to the Heads of <strong>State</strong> and Government: Strengthening the International Financial Architecture, available at<br />

http://www.g7.utoronto.ca/finance/fm20000708-st.html.<br />

21. See generally Uofr G8 Information Centre: Gleneagles Documents,<br />

http://www.g7.utoronto.ca/summit/2005gleneagles/index.html.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 794 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 795<br />

This author suggests that the thrust of the G7/G8 financial sector reform<br />

mandates over the past decade can be seen as geared to the following policy<br />

concerns:<br />

- Financial Crisis Avoidance and Resolution;<br />

- Financial Stability;<br />

- Financial Services Liberalization; and<br />

- Regional and Global Cooperation.<br />

More recently, financial sector reform also has been driven by industrialized<br />

country concern for financial sector integrity, which has come to embrace the<br />

following:<br />

- Anti-Money Laundering (drug dealing and other criminal activities);<br />

- Combating Terrorism Financing;<br />

- Anti-Corruption;<br />

- Corporate Governance of Financial Institutions;<br />

- Transparency and Accountability; and<br />

- Greater Availability of Information and Enhanced Disclosure."<br />

While one can reasonably and in good faith rationalize that these focal points<br />

are directly related to the economic development processes of developing countries,<br />

the truth is that these concerns have been engendered as a result of industrialized<br />

country interests, and that in many of these instances the interconnection with<br />

substantive development goals of poverty reduction is indirect and sometimes<br />

tenuous at best. 23<br />

That said, the bottom line is that the role of the IFIs in the area of financial<br />

sector reform over the past decade has been mandated largely by the G7/8 global<br />

policy determinations and directives.<br />

B. NIFA and the Role of International Standards: An Industrialized Country<br />

Initiative<br />

As alluded to above, the G7/G8 directed a number of international<br />

organizations to develop and implement international prudential standards<br />

("codes") in order to encourage and improve confidence in and viability of domestic<br />

financial systems. Such standards were aimed at promoting sound financial<br />

institutions, minimizing systemic risk, and encouraging savings and investment<br />

activity through increased confidence in financial markets, both domestically and<br />

22. World Bank, World Bank and AML/CFT, http://wwwl.worldbank.org/finance/html/amlcft/ (last<br />

visited Oct. 12, 2006).<br />

23. For example, having "Basel-compliant" banking systems is a good goal for all countriesdeveloped<br />

and developing-but for a developing country it does not really get to the core issue of how the<br />

banking and financial system should best be structured to serve optimum country-specific socioeconomic<br />

development needs. Also, while of key concern to the U.S. and other highly industrialized countries'<br />

efforts in their so-called "global war on terrorism," it is quite dubious that the amount of efforts<br />

development banks now spend on the areas of anti-money laundering and counterterrorism financing<br />

produces any real development benefits that would justify the cost and effort.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 795 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

internationally. It must be noted at the outset, however, that these international<br />

principles and standards were to be just that: minimum internationally accepted<br />

guidelines that leave latitude in their implementation. 24<br />

The G7 Finance Ministers were impressed with the prior work of the Basel<br />

Committee and IOSCO on developing "international standards for prudential<br />

supervision" of banks, securities firms, and markets, as well as payment and<br />

settlement systems. In particular, the Ministers approved joint Basel<br />

Committee/IOSCO work on market risk and capital adequacy, as well as derivatives<br />

and futures exchanges-sophisticated areas of concern for the industrialized<br />

countries. The Ministers also recognized the cooperation among the bank,<br />

securities, and insurance supervisors through the Joint Forum and recommended<br />

better vehicles for increased institutional cooperation. With hindsight, one can see<br />

from this thread the subsequent increased importance and spread of international<br />

standards and codes and the later formation of the international standards<br />

coordinator, the Financial Stability Forum."<br />

Quite clearly, the development of international banking standards by the Basel<br />

Committee long predates the emergence of the NIFA. In fact, in 1974 the Ministers<br />

of Finance and Central Bank Governors of the "Group of 10,,26 became concerned<br />

with possible development of international bank supervisory standards in response<br />

to the interrelated insolvencies of two small international banks (the German<br />

Bankhaus Herstatt and the American Franklin National Bank) that had resulted<br />

from excessive exchange rate risks and the lack of coordinated supervision by the<br />

concerned regulatory authorities to address this problem. Therefore, in 1975, they<br />

established what is now the Basel Committee. 27 Regarding this incident, the<br />

governors of the Central Bank were not concerned about any specific systemic crisis.<br />

However, it dawned on them that there was no established mechanism for<br />

coordinating cross-border supervision of banking institutions that faced increased<br />

international risks in the new 1970s era of global floating exchange rates. In<br />

addition, the governor of the Bank of England was becoming concerned that capital<br />

adequacy of banking institutions was turning into an issue of international import;<br />

traditionally, bank regulators/supervisors were primarily concerned with institutional<br />

liquidity. As such, the first tasks of the Basel Committee were to consider cross-<br />

24. See G7 Finance Ministers, Lyon, France: June 27-29, 1996, Report to the Heads of <strong>State</strong> and<br />

Government on International Monetary Stability, http://www.g7.utoronto.ca/summit/19961yon/finance.html<br />

(last visited Sept. 29, 2006).<br />

25. See id.<br />

26. The G10 Group came about in 1974 as a consequence of the establishment in 1962 of the General<br />

Agreement to Borrow (GAB) pursuant to decision of the Executive Board of the International Monetary<br />

Fund. The Group was informally established with the support of the IMF, OECD, the Bank for<br />

International Settlement, by the finance ministers of Belgium, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the<br />

Netherlands, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the United <strong>State</strong>s for the primary purpose of<br />

intergovernmental consulting regarding implementation of calls upon the lines of credit extended to the<br />

IMF under the GAB-the scope of such consultation being broadened over the years. Subsequently,<br />

Switzerland has become an active member of the Group, rendering the "G10" designation a misnomer.<br />

The G10 Group operates through the respective finance ministers on the highest level, but also on specific<br />

subject-matters through various ad hoc committees. See generally Group of Ten homepage, available at<br />

http://www.oecd.org/document/32/0,2340,en_2649_34115_36191264_1_1_1_1,00.html.<br />

27. Reference to the founding mandate for the Basel Committee from the Governors of the Central<br />

Banks of the GIO countries can be found in a Press Communiqu6 of the G10 Central Bank Governors of<br />

Feb. 12, 1975, issued through the BIS.<br />

28. See NORTON, supra note 7, ch. 4, sec. IIA.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 796 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 797<br />

border supervision and capital adequacy. The objects of this focus were<br />

international banks of the industrialized countries comprising the membership of the<br />

Basel Committee. 9<br />

During the 1980s, the Basel Committee produced a revised framework,<br />

"Concordat," for attempting to allocate international bank supervisory authority<br />

among the host and home regulator/supervisor; a rather sketchy version had been<br />

quietly put together in 1975.30 This framework was revised on several occasions<br />

during the remainder of the 1980s and the 1990s, largely as a reaction to specific<br />

bank failures exposing the framework's inadequacies." Also, during the mid-1990s,<br />

it became apparent that the "international banking institution" was an incomplete<br />

notion for supervision of the large industrialized banks as they tended to operate<br />

more and more within the structure of banking and financial "conglomerates."<br />

Thus, a supervisory framework for dealing with these conglomerates also was<br />

developed. 32 This, in turn, led to a consideration of the issue of the "lead regulator"<br />

as to such conglomerates. 33<br />

The most significant efforts of the Committee from the 1980s to present have<br />

been on risk-based capital adequacy standards. After extended, and at times<br />

contentious, internal deliberations, a risk-based "Capital Adequacy Accord" was<br />

promulgated by the Committee in 1988. 3 1 While a non-binding, non-official<br />

document, this Accord soon (through a complex, informal, and uncoordinated<br />

transmission matrix) became the international benchmark for bank capital adequacy<br />

within the developed and then-developing world. 35 Prior to this Accord, the capital<br />

approach taken by most bank regulators/supervisors was a basic initial capitalization<br />

requirement and then an ongoing requirement of some form of fixed capital-based<br />

ratio (e.g., capital to assets). 36 At the time, the 1988 Accord was thought to be a most<br />

complex approach, while today it is considered a basic, rudimentary framework<br />

when compared to the Committee's current proposal, the Basel II Accord. 37<br />

In a sense, the 1988 Capital Accord opened Pandora's box as to the future<br />

formulation of international bank standards. Once a risk-based approach became<br />

the guiding measure, it became logical for the Basel Committee to delve into a range<br />

of other risks, such as exchange rates, interest rates, and other market-based and<br />

29. See W.P. Cooke in Basle Supervisors Committee (June 21, 1984) (providing discussion of role of<br />

Committee in document for external distribution).<br />

30. The first public appearance of the 1975 Concordat was as an Annex ("Supervision of Banks'<br />

Foreign Establishments") to R.C. Williams and G.G. Johnson, International Capital Markets: Recent<br />

Developments and Short-Term Prospects, 29-32 (IMF Occasional Paper No. 7, 1981).<br />

31. See, e.g., DOUGLAS ARNER, FINANCIAL STABILITY, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND THE ROLE OF<br />

LAW (forthcoming 2007).<br />

32. See George A. Walker, The <strong>Law</strong> of Financial Conglomerates: The Next Generation, 30 INT'L LAW.<br />

57, 57 (1996).<br />

33. See George A. Walker, Conglomerate <strong>Law</strong> and International Financial Market Supervision, 17<br />

ANN. REV. BANKING L. 287,293 (1998).<br />

34. Basel Committee, International Convergence of Capital Measurement and Capital Standards (July<br />

1988), available at http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbsclll.pdf.<br />

35. See Joseph Jude Norton, Capital Adequacy Standards: A Legitimate Regulatory Concern for<br />

Prudential Supervision of Banking Activities?, 49 OHIO ST. L.J. 1299,1342 (1989).<br />

36. See, e.g., JOSEPH JUDE NORTON & SHERRY CASTLE WHITLEY, BANKING LAW MANUAL, ch. 3<br />

(1995).<br />

37. See Basel Committee, supra note 34; But cf, Basel Committee, International Convergence of<br />

Capital Measurement and Capital Standards (June 2006), available at http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs128.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 797 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

operational risks. These activities resulted in a series of other detailed Committee<br />

pronouncements. Beginning in the late 1980s and continuing on to today, the<br />

Committee became concerned with money laundering 38 and related counterterrorism<br />

regulatory standards. 9 Then, in the late 1990s, the Committee began to address the<br />

issues of institutional governance more formally as to banking institutions."<br />

Under the NIFA context, international standards and codes have evolved,<br />

increasing as to subject-matter and continuing to be refined on the basis of global<br />

and industrial country experiences and expectations. In this sense, they represent<br />

the model components for a country's "modern" financial system, and they may be<br />

utilized for multiple purposes. For example, an individual country may use<br />

international standards to reform its domestic financial system. These codes and<br />

standards may also comprise a part of IMF and Bank "conditionality" programs.<br />

Additionally, they might be employed by an IFI in fulfilling requests for technical<br />

assistance packages. Or, they might be used by the IMF in its ROSCmacroeconomic<br />

surveillance efforts, or, more flexibly, by the Bank to assess<br />

domestic financial infrastructures for development projects. No matter what the<br />

application, on-the-ground reform work over the past two decades has shown<br />

repeatedly that the introduction of standards and codes is a top-down model, that<br />

each country's situation is sui generis, and that these standards and codes have not<br />

been designed as developmental access instruments.'<br />

III. THE WORLD BANK'S NEW AGENDA ON FINANCIAL ACCESS AND<br />

EQUITY ISSUES<br />

Inherently, the IFIs/RFIs represent an enormous repository of accumulated<br />

knowledge of policies, theories, issues, and practices concerning the Developing<br />

World. They are in a real sense socioeconomic and legal development knowledge<br />

banks. As such, they should be in the best position to help influence and guide the<br />

much-needed connection between financial sector development and meaningful<br />

economic development goals respecting their developing client countries. This is<br />

often easier said than done for a variety of overriding practical reasons. For<br />

example, these RFI/IFIs tend to be complex bureaucracies, with enormous internal<br />

and external competition over their limited human and financial resources. These<br />

institutional demands have expanded exponentially over the past several decades,<br />

covering not simply traditional macroeconomic development concerns, but also a<br />

broad range of microeconomic matters, macro- and micro-financial sector concerns,<br />

human capital development issues (the encapsulating one of which is poverty<br />

alleviation), societal dilemmas such as gender issues, global human migration, and<br />

fundamental human rights concerns. As can been seen, financial sector issues are<br />

only one of many pressing demands upon IFI/RFI resources.<br />

38. See, e.g., Basel Committee, Prevention of Criminal Use of the Banking System for the Purpose of<br />

Money Laundering (Dec. 1988) available at http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbsc137.pdf.<br />

39. See, e.g., Basel Committee, Initiatives by the BCBS, IAIS and IOSCO to Combat Money<br />

Laundering and the Financing of Terrorism: Update (Jan. 2005), available at<br />

http://www.bis.org/publ/jointll.pdf.<br />

40. See, e.g., Basel Committee, Enhancing Corporate Governance for Banking Organisations (1999),<br />

available at http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs56.pdf; see also Feb. 2006 revision, available at<br />

http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs122.pdf.<br />

41. See generally NORTON, supra note 7.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 798 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 799<br />

Coherent and forward-looking institutional priority-setting by the IFI/RFIs is<br />

difficult, time-consuming, and often contentious. These various institutions may<br />

have differing mandates and approaches to these mandates. Historically,<br />

collaboration among these institutions has been marginal at best. In addition, as<br />

discussed above, the IFI/RFI general focus on financial sector reform and specific<br />

focus on the legal-institutional aspect thereof is a relatively recent "add-on"<br />

dimension of these institutions, mandated by the G7/G8 and arising in large part as a<br />

reaction to financial crises, the need for global financial stability, and concerns over<br />

money laundering and terrorist financing. In addressing these financial sector<br />

demands, the IFIs/RFIs have largely looked to standards of industrialized countries,<br />

engaging in large measure staff and consultants drawn from the industrialized world<br />

(people, incidentally, having significant financial sector experience in their country,<br />

but little, if any, development background and experience).<br />

A bright light in this quagmire is that most recently the IFIs/RFIs, in particular<br />

the World Bank, are beginning to focus in a more comprehensive way on the<br />

"missing component" to viable banking and financial sector legal reform in<br />

developing countries: the inclusion of the Developing World population. Through<br />

this focus reorientation, it may be possible for these institutions to better set and<br />

develop their own internal priorities in this area of reform. This will allow them to<br />

be of greater assistance to their Developing Country members in developing and<br />

coordinating meaningful policies, institutions, and legal infrastructure with a view to<br />

building more relevant, accessible, and equitable financial sectors.<br />

In this context, it is of significance that the World Bank dedicated its entire<br />

World Development Report 2006 to the theme of "Equity and Development." 42 This<br />

Report, the work-product of the Bank's staff, considers equity in terms of "two basic<br />

principles": equal opportunity and avoidance of income deprivation. 43 The report<br />

highlights that legal and regulatory frameworks and equitable justice systems can do<br />

much to level the playing field in the political, economic, and sociocultural domains,<br />

but can also reinforce existing inequalities.' In addition, in anticipation of this<br />

report, the Bank's Legal Vice Presidency (LVP), then under Hon. Roberto Dafiino,<br />

perceptively held an extended high-level forerunner conference in December 2005<br />

on "<strong>Law</strong>, Equity and Development." The primary purpose of this event was to<br />

explore ways the LVP and the Bank should best approach matters of legal and<br />

justice reform, including how to move the LVP forward to the next generation of<br />

financial sector legal reform." This event was followed up and expanded upon by<br />

another major World Bank Conference in spring 2006 on a wide range of issues<br />

concerning "access and equality" in economic and financial development. 6<br />

For illustrative purposes, Part III highlights two other significant developments<br />

at the World Bank with respect to financial sector access issues. First, the Bank<br />

recently commissioned a series of reports concerning access to financial services in<br />

42. World Bank, World Development Report 2006: Equity and Development (2005).<br />

43. Id.<br />

44. Id.<br />

45. This conference was held on Dec. 1-2, 2005 at the IFC in Washington, DC.<br />

46. See World Bank (Financial Sector), Global Conference on Access to Finance: Building Inclusive<br />

Financial Systems (Washington, D.C., May 30-31. 2006). available at<br />

http://web.worldbank.orgfWBSITE/EXTERNALIWBIWBIPROGRAMSIFSLP/0,,contentMDK:2061156<br />

0-pagePK:64156158-piPK:64152884-theSitePK:461005,00.html.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 799 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

Latin America. Hopefully, these and other country reports from the Bank will<br />

provide a good comparative data- and policy base for the Bank and its LVP to begin<br />

to formulate a "next generation" approach to bank/financial sector legal reform<br />

respecting developing countries. The second Bank development is the expanded<br />

actual and potential role that the Bank, with the IMF, is beginning to make of its<br />

FSAPs and related country Financial Sector Assessments for purposes of fostering<br />

financial sector access and equity.<br />

A. The Country Studies<br />

The thematic strand that unifies the four World Bank studies discussed below,<br />

which previous studies have glossed over, is that the definition of financial access<br />

must be broadened. The definition is now seen not only to include the ability for<br />

small businesses or individuals to obtain loans, but also to hold checking and savings<br />

accounts, utilize debit and credit cards, pay for services at a branch or ATM instead<br />

of only at a downtown office, and gain access to investment opportunities. These<br />

studies all examine the methods of savings and how cultural, environmental, and<br />

socioeconomic factors come into play in creating poverty. Government policies,<br />

such as excessive reserve requirements, play a large role in reinforcing cycles of<br />

poverty. Further, the studies find that access to technology can play a large role in<br />

alleviating cycles of poverty by allowing the poor easier access to services. These<br />

four studies are the following:<br />

Poverty Reduction and Growth: Virtuous and Vicious Circles,<br />

47 which examines<br />

the essential question of how cycles of poverty reinforce themselves and what<br />

policies can be put into place to break those cycles;<br />

Access to Financial Services in Brazil,<br />

48 which examines specific issues in Brazil<br />

and highlights their implications to government policy;<br />

Access to Financial Services in Colombia: The "Unbanked" in Bogota, 9 which<br />

lie outside the formal economy and why inclusion is necessary to economic<br />

development and progress in Columbia and<br />

Urban Unbanked in Mexico and the United <strong>State</strong>s, ° which compares the<br />

differences between access to financial services for the poor in both countries.<br />

1. Virtuous and Vicious Circles. Written in 2005, this study explores in depth<br />

the search for pro-poor growth. It is well known that such growth can increase<br />

income to the poor and alleviate poverty.<br />

The reverse thesis has not been sufficiently explored and provides the thesis for<br />

this study: that vicious circles exist where low growth results in high poverty and high<br />

poverty, in turn, results in low growth." The more novel thesis of the report is that<br />

47. GUILLERMO E. PERRY ET AL., POVERTY REDUCTION AND GROWTH: VIRTUOUS AND VICIOUS<br />

CIRCLES (2006).<br />

48. ANJALI KUMAR, ACCESS TO FINANCIAL SERVICES IN BRAZIL (2005).<br />

49. Tova Maria Solo & Astrid Manroth, Access to Financial Services in Colombia: The "Unbanked" in<br />

Bogotd, (World Bank Policy Research, Working Paper No. 3834, 2006), available at<br />

http://web.worldbank.orgfWBSITE/EXTERNALIWBI/WBIPROGRAMS/FSLP/0,,contentMDK:2061 162<br />

8-pagePK:64156158-piPK:64152884-theSitePK:461005,00.html.<br />

50. John Caskey et al., The Urban Unbanked in Mexico and the United <strong>State</strong>s (World Bank Policy<br />

Research, Working Paper No. 3835, 2006), available at http://ideas.repec.org/p/wbk/wbrwps/3835.html.<br />

51. See PERRY ET AL., supra note 47, at 41.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 800 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 801<br />

Latin America's persistent poverty may itself be impeding the achievement of higher<br />

growth rates, implying that there are reinforcing vicious circles keeping the poor in<br />

poverty and from contributing to national growth. 2<br />

In light of the study's findings, the question of whether financial policies should<br />

emphasize pro-growth or pro-poor can be answered simply: "Yes." Strategies that<br />

do not focus on growth ignore the greatest means that governments and institutions<br />

have at their disposal for improving human well-being. These same institutions and<br />

governments must also take into account the constraints facing the impoverished to<br />

enable the poor to fully participate in any growth, thereby contributing back to the<br />

wave of growth. This study describes the process of redressing these constraints and<br />

brings to light an under-examined dimension of policy analysis that might be called<br />

pro-growth poverty reduction. 3<br />

This study shows that in order to achieve the greatest reduction in poverty, the<br />

relative emphasis on growth versus redistribution should vary depending on the<br />

individual country's initial conditions." Poor countries with relative equality, such as<br />

Bolivia, Haiti, and Honduras, "have little to distribute [and] need first and foremost<br />

high and sustained growth, even at the expense of some increases in inequality." 55<br />

The paper compares this kind of growth to the growth recently experienced in<br />

China." In contrast, countries with relatively greater wealth and inequality,<br />

including much of Latin America-particularly Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, and<br />

Mexico- need both higher growth and significant redistribution to begin the process<br />

of reducing poverty. 7<br />

The poverty traps described in chapter six of this study apply to both national<br />

and regional areas equally. 8 Regional traps must take into account that within<br />

countries, labor does not move freely. This creates large wage gaps of up to fifty<br />

percent from region to region. 9<br />

This study shows that the disparity in income inequality between Latin America<br />

and contemporary Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development<br />

countries is due in part to "differences in returns to factors of production-the result<br />

of the unequal distribution of human and other capital in Latin America." 6 ° Another<br />

reason for this disparity is "the generally unprogressive nature of Latin America's<br />

system of transfers." 61 Countries in Latin America heavily fund both progressive and<br />

regressive programs, which offset each other. 62 The study's conclusion is that a<br />

country's financial history is not its destiny. The decline in Latin America's income<br />

position in the last fifty years, compared with the OECD member nations' sharp<br />

reductions in inequality during the same period, demonstrates that choices of<br />

policies and institutions can lead to major improvements along both dimensions. 63<br />

52. See id.<br />

53. See id.<br />

54. Id. at 4.<br />

55. Id.<br />

56. Id.<br />

57. PERRY ET AL., supra note 47, at 4.<br />

58. See generally id. at 103-26.<br />

59. Id. at 138.<br />

60. Id. at 4.<br />

61. Id.<br />

62. Id. at 5.<br />

63. PERRY ET AL., supra note 47, at 4.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 801 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

For example, increased access to education and infrastructure has encouraged<br />

growth, inequality, and poverty reduction; other policies, such as trade opening, have<br />

encouraged growth while increasing inequality and poverty in the short run. 4 These<br />

short-term issues can be mitigated by better policy considerations so that, in the long<br />

run, these pro-growth policies will lead to more financial equality. 6 1<br />

2. Access to Financial Services in Brazil. The objective of the present study is<br />

to identify ways of expanding access while acknowledging the risks and costs<br />

involved and providing measures to mitigate their impact. The largest financial<br />

system in Latin America is Brazil; "beyond its sheer size, the overall depth of<br />

financial intermediation in Brazil, at almost 140% of gross domestic product, is<br />

greater than those of its large neighbors in the region such as Mexico and Argentina,<br />

despite their higher average per capita income." 66 With numerous banks in decline<br />

since the late 1990s, concern about financial exclusion has increased over the last<br />

decade despite Brazil's size. An estimated sixty million, or approximately one-third,<br />

67<br />

of Brazil's population have bank accounts.<br />

Brazil's policies, which attempt to provide credit to the poor, have a high cost.<br />

These costs have another unintended result: the government's large borrowing<br />

needs have a negative impact on private credit. Large reserve requirements add to<br />

implicit taxation. Some more conservative estimates suggest that concessions and<br />

support could amount to several billion Reais. 68 Unfortunately, Brazil's policies<br />

themselves may also be ineffective in reaching the poorest and those most in need of<br />

financial access.<br />

An example of the cost and failure of Brazil's policies is the National Program<br />

to Strengthen Family Agriculture (PRONAF) which is estimated to cost R$1.1<br />

billion. 69 The top two percent of borrowers receive fifty-seven percent of loans in<br />

agriculture, whereas the lowest seventy-five percent of borrowers receive only six<br />

percent of credit. 70 As illustrated by the analysis of rural finance programs, many<br />

such programs fail to reach their intended targets, instead they are captured by a few<br />

individuals, to the detriment of broad-based access.<br />

There is a role for more proactive government policies toward access to<br />

financial services. However, the success of these policies will be the greatest if they<br />

are backed by fundamental changes in overall approach to access. This approach<br />

must be delivered through broad-based financial sector reforms that limit constraints<br />

on the price and quantity of credit. Finally, the role given to the relatively small<br />

number of public institutions charged with delivering these policies must be reduced<br />

in order to ensure fair access.<br />

3. Access to Financial Services in Colombia: The "Unbanked" in Bogota.<br />

Supported by the Colombian Bank Association, this study finds that access to<br />

financial services is a determinant in a country's development and that access to<br />

financial services translates into progress. 7 The study quotes Ross Levine's<br />

statement that "[n]o shortage of evidence exists to suggest that the level of financial<br />

64. Id.<br />

65. Id.<br />

66. KUMAR, supra note 48, at xxviii.<br />

67. Id. at xxi.<br />

68. Id. at xxii.<br />

69. Id. at 280.<br />

70. Id.<br />

71. See generally Solo & Manroth, supra note 49.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 802 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 803<br />

development is a good indicator of economic growth, capital accumulation and of<br />

the technological change of the future economy." 72 The study takes a specific look at<br />

the financial situation in Bogota and what life is like outside the formal financial<br />

system. For example, one family who moved to Bogota in the 1950s attempted to<br />

build their home through self-help and ended up paying twice the cost of their<br />

home. 73<br />

The study is harshly critical of the continuation of the government's tax on<br />

financial transactions that was originally intended to be a temporary solution to the<br />

banking crisis in Columbia. The tax has now been made a permanent one and has<br />

been increased from 0.2% to 0.4%. Financial exclusion in the country has created<br />

significant welfare losses, a declining savings rate, and a financial system that caters<br />

to the wealthy through monthly fees that equal 5-10% of the minimum wage."<br />

The study explains that an effective financial sector reduces the cost of<br />

information sharing between economic agents and that the current trend does not<br />

look positive for the country. Though the unbanked are often paid by check, they<br />

have no access to financial institutions. As a result, they are forced to pay large<br />

check cashing fees and do business in remote central bank locations. Further, to<br />

obtain credit, every individual or small business must approach potential lenders one<br />

by one to obtain the amount and terms that they require.<br />

The costs of these factors inhibit growth in general. This has created an<br />

alternative system whereby many individuals save and borrow primarily through<br />

friends and family, and their primary savings is tied to home ownership. This<br />

alternative method cuts off their financial resources from the nation or region and<br />

hinders growth.<br />

4. The Urban Unbanked in Mexico and the United <strong>State</strong>s. This study examines<br />

how impoverished households in the United <strong>State</strong>s and Mexico obtain basic financial<br />

services. It also examines the efforts that the private sector and government have<br />

taken to provide access to these services, both in terms of cost and quality. The<br />

different ways in which the unbanked operate in the United <strong>State</strong>s and Mexico<br />

provides an instructive contrast, illustrating how policies can be effective and how<br />

policies must differ based on cultural differences in saving and investing.<br />

The differing private sector approaches by the U.S. and Mexico illustrate the<br />

link between broader coverage of financial services and economic growth. The<br />

savings and loan crisis experienced in the U.S. in the 1980s did not cause a major<br />

sector collapse because U.S. banks had spread their business over a wider gamut and<br />

depended on a variety of population sectors in addition to the wealthy. This can be<br />

contrasted with the similar situations experienced in Mexico and Colombia that did<br />

cause major financial crises.<br />

Experience also shows that financial institutions catering to low-income clients<br />

can be good businesses. Recent studies by the U.S. Federal Reserve have favorably<br />

compared the profitability of investments under the Community Reinvestment Act<br />

credits to commercial investments. These studies have also shown the profitability<br />

72. Id. at 10 (citing Ross Levine, Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda,<br />

35 J. ECON. LITERATURE 688 (1997)).<br />

73. Id. at 7.<br />

74. Dr. Mauricio Herra-Baquero, financial and economic development law expert, of the Externado<br />

University <strong>Law</strong> faculty in Bogota has advised the authors of these subsequent events.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 803 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

of community development financing institutions as favorable to other start-up<br />

banks. 7<br />

The differences between the unbanked in Mexico and the United <strong>State</strong>s are<br />

striking. One study showed that in the United <strong>State</strong>s, where there are multiple<br />

alternatives, check cashing services can often charge a fee of 2-3%. 7 1 In Mexico,<br />

where there are few practical alternatives, there are no fees for check cashing<br />

services. 7 ' This shows that significant differences exist and any approach to solving<br />

issues must take into account those differences: there is no one-size-fits-all solution.<br />

Consider the above studies; the challenges facing the impoverished in obtaining<br />

financial assistance are at best difficult and at worst impossible. The collective<br />

observations of these four studies reaffirms that although the poor face challenges,<br />

there is much work that can be done to alleviate the severity of these cycles of<br />

poverty. There are common policies that can be implemented across Latin America<br />

which would go a long way to improving the situation the unbanked in those<br />

countries face.<br />

B. FSAPs: One Possible Supporting Pillar for the "Next Generation" of Financial<br />

Sector Legal reform.<br />

Coming out of the 1998 Birmingham and 1999 Cologne G8 Summits, the IFIs<br />

received mandates to both internally evaluate the effectiveness of their IFI reform<br />

programs, and more broadly to develop assessment mechanisms concerning the<br />

condition of the financial sector as a whole with recommendations for reform.<br />

Underlying the policy is the thought that identification of financial system strengths<br />

and vulnerabilities will help promote financial stability and reduce the potential for<br />

crisis. These mandates have led to the enhancement of IMF surveillance<br />

mechanisms, to the establishment of independent internal offices, and to the<br />

establishment of a joint IMF-World Bank Financial Sector Assessment Program<br />

(FSAP), beginning with a joint pilot program in 1999.8 Based on the initial success<br />

of the pilot program, the joint FSAP program was refined and formalized on an<br />

ongoing basis, with this initiative being coordinated through an IMF-World Bank<br />

Financial Sector Liaison Committee. 79 As conceived, the FSAP<br />

... is widely recognized by participating countries and by the international<br />

community as an important instrument for diagnosis of potential<br />

vulnerabilities and analysis of development priorities in the financial<br />

sectors of member countries .... One objective of the FSAP is to help<br />

countries map a transition to a more diversified and competitive financial<br />

sector without creating vulnerabilities. A well-functioning financial<br />

75. See generally, William C. Apgar and Mark Deida, The Twenty-fifth Anniversary of the Community<br />

Reinvestment Act: Past Accomplishment and Future Regulatory Challenges, FED. RES. ECON. POL. REv.<br />

169 (June 2003).<br />

76. Caskey et al., supra note 50, at 8, 22.<br />

77. Id. at 41.<br />

78. See Staff of IMF and World Bank, Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP)- A Review:<br />

Lessons from the Pilot and Issues Going Forward, available at<br />

www.imf.org/external/np/fsap/2000/review.htm#tabl.<br />

79. IMF & World Bank, Financial Sector Assessment Program -Review, Lessons, and Issues Going<br />

Forward 5 (Feb. 24, 2003), available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/fsap/2003/review.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 804 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 805<br />

services sector is essential for sustained economic development and<br />

poverty reduction. The existence of a wide and diversified set of sound,<br />

well-managed institutions and markets also reduces the likelihood and<br />

magnitude of a financial crisis.<br />

Thus, from its inauguration, in order to accommodate the differing institutional<br />

missions of the IMF and the Bank, the FSAP initiative has been articulated in terms<br />

of bifurcated objectives: (i) financial crisis prevention and financial stability and (ii)<br />

economic development and poverty reduction. 8 This author suggests that these<br />

objectives are not necessarily coextensive nor fully compatible. Further, this author<br />

would note that in terms of the Bank's mandate, these objectives gloss over what a<br />

well-functioning financial services sector should mean in terms of economic<br />

development and poverty reduction. Moreover, the causal linkage between the<br />

modern financial sector model envisioned by the FSAP criteria and instruments and<br />

actual poverty reduction has never been empirically substantiated. This being said<br />

the Bank's stated FSAP objective might provide the context within which to<br />

determine how best the FSAP process can be utilized as a catalytic and supportive<br />

vehicle for the next generation of financial sector reform.<br />

Functionally, FSAP is requested voluntarily by a country and is normally<br />

effected over several joint IMF-Bank team missions. 2 Upon completion, the team<br />

prepares an aide-memoir presenting the findings. 83 This non-published, confidential<br />

document will be used by the IMF to prepare a Financial Sector Stability<br />

Assessment (FSSA) for presentation to its Executive Board, and is often used also in<br />

connection with the Fund's surveillance role under its biennial Article IV<br />

consultations. The Bank staff will use the aide-memoir to put together a Financial<br />

Sector Assessment for its Executive Board 5<br />

The FSAP itself entails three main components: (i) systematic analysis of<br />

financial soundness indicators (FSIs) and stress tests; (ii) assessments of standards<br />

and codes; and (iii) assessment of the broader financial stability framework,<br />

including systemic liquidity arrangements, governance and transparency, and<br />

financial safety nets and insolvency regimesYi The FSAP work has come to support<br />

the IMF's role in the standards and code area and to support the Bank's<br />

development efforts (particularly as to technical assistance), including its Country<br />

Assistance Strategies.<br />

The FSAP is separate from, but substantively linked to, the IMF's role as to the<br />

Reports on Observance of Standards and Codes initiative (ROSC initiative).<br />

According to the Bank, there are three reasons for its participation in the ROSC<br />

initiative:<br />

80. ld. at 4, para 1.<br />

81. G7 Finance Ministers, supra note 18.<br />

82. Id. at 25.<br />

83. These are not published. Prior to March 2003, FSAP teams prepared more lengthy FSAP reports.<br />

84. The author has been advised by a World Bank official experienced with FSAPs that this is the<br />

procedure that has been internally developed.<br />

85. On the nature and workings of the FSAPs, see generally World Bank/IMF, FINANCIAL SECTOR<br />

ASSESSMENT: A HANDBOOK (2005).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 805 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

- "[The] structural and institutional underpinnings of a market economy are an<br />

important complement to sound macroeconomic policies for both successful<br />

integration with the world economy and for sound development[;]"<br />

- "[Ijmplementation of standards can help countries establish these<br />

foundations, in turn contributing to national and global financial stability[;]" and<br />

- "[P]artnership with the IMF provides the basis for a comprehensive approach<br />

and broad-based effort on the implementation of standards." ''<br />

However, the FSAP, at least for the Bank, utilizes particular codes and<br />

standards selectively and more flexibly (in consultation with the host country), and<br />

may deal with standards not formally under the ROSC (e.g., creditors rights and<br />

corporate insolvency, deposit insurance and bank insolvency), and will deal with<br />

cross-sectoral issues. In recent years, the Bank has been attempting to integrate the<br />

FSAP, FSA, and ROSC processes into its evolving development agenda.m Notably,<br />

this integration effort has begun to address the developmental context of the overall<br />

financial legal infrastructures and issues of access.<br />

The FSAP process for the Bank has its limitations in addressing the<br />

developmental context and content of the "next generation" of financial sector legal<br />

reform. The process is a joint institutional effort with divergent overall objectives. It<br />

is conducted by a joint institution team and is a complex technical process.<br />

However, the FSAP is also a flexible data gathering process that most probably can<br />

be better and more broadly utilized by the Bank and its LVP in evaluating, revising,<br />

and prioritizing its financial sector reform policy objectives and related technical<br />

assistance. Certainly, this is well worth serious consideration by the Bank and its<br />

LVP and the IMF.<br />

IV. Two CURRENT DEVELOPMENTS OF SIGNIFICANCE:<br />

MICROFINANCING AND PRIVATE INDUSTRY PARTICIPATION<br />

In looking selectively at recent developments in the financial access area as to<br />

developing countries, two potential institutional developments are worth noting for<br />

present purposes: (i) the rise of microfinancing and (ii) private banking industry<br />

initiatives in South Africa.<br />

A. Microfinancing<br />

With the recent Nobel Peace Prize award to Muhammad Yunus of the Grameen<br />

Bank in India for his and his bank's work with developing microfinance products for<br />

the poor and expanding the use of such products on a commercially viable basis,9 it<br />

seems microfinance is a new discovery. The reality, however, is that microfinancing<br />

has been around at least since the 1950s, having a very spotty record of success until<br />

86. IMF & World Bank, Assessing the Implementation of Standards: A Review of Experience and Next<br />

Steps 26 (Jan. 11, 2001), available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/sac/2001/eng/review.pdf.<br />

87. Id. ch. 5.<br />

88. Id. ch 4.<br />

89. See generally NobelPrize.org, The Nobel Prize 2006,<br />

http://nobelprize.org/nobel-prizes/peace/laureates/2006.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 806 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 807<br />

more recent times. 90 The recently formed Consultative Group for Assisting the<br />

Poorest, a consortium of donor countries affiliated with the World Bank, has<br />

brought microfinancing into the mainstream of the IFI development agenda.<br />

1. Background<br />

Microfinance, along with credit and national savings structures for small- and<br />

medium-sized enterprises has come to be viewed as of major importance for<br />

enhancing the social and economic impact of the financial sector of developing<br />

countries. 9 Microfinance today is seen as a vital tool against poverty since it directly<br />

provides to low-income people the tools to build assets, increase and protect their<br />

source of income, and reach self-sufficiency. For example, in Latin America (which<br />

will be the geographic focus of Part IV(A)), microfinance institutions started being<br />

established in the 1980s with the arrival of non-governmental organizations (NGOs)<br />

making loans to poor "microentrepreneurs." In 1992, the Bolivian NGO,<br />

PRODERM, was converted into the first regulated MFI in Latin America-<br />

BancoSol, a regulated commercial bank. 92<br />

Today, it is probably safe to argue that Latin America has the longest tradition<br />

of commercially viable microfinance. In fact, competition tends to be intense in<br />

some countries, especially in urban areas, and interest rates in some countries have<br />

declined dramatically as a result of that competition. For instance, in Bolivia,<br />

market pioneer BancoSol charged a combination of interest and fees equivalent to a<br />

sixty-five percent annual percentage rate when it began operating as a bank in 1992.<br />

Today, BancoSol operates in a highly competitive environment and has brought its<br />

interest rate down to twenty-two percent. " In addition, "leading institutions are<br />

increasingly offering a variety of financial services to their clients, including savings<br />

and management of international and domestic funds transfers.""<br />

2. Improvement of Microfinance<br />

Despite some degree of market penetration to date and a variety of financial<br />

services offered in some Latin American countries, there remains significant<br />

opportunities in larger Latin American countries where little microfinancing is<br />

currently occurring (e.g., Mexico and Brazil), in secondary cities and in rural areas. 95<br />

Despite media hype, only a small percentage of SMEs at the moment have access to<br />

90. For a discussion on microfinancing, see generally the CGAP's extensive website on the matter,<br />

available at http://cgap.org/portal/site/cgap.<br />

91. See generally International Year of Microcredit, E.S.C. Res.1998/28, U.N. ESCOR, 45th mtg.,<br />

U.N. Doc. A/RES/53/197 (Feb. 22, 1999).<br />

92. On BancoSol generally, including its history and development, see<br />

www.bancosol.combo/en/historia/htm. In addition, on this site there is a separate link<br />

"historiamicro.e.pdf" that contains a detailed discussion of the history of microfinance in Latin America.<br />

Though some trace this development to the 1960s creation of ACCION International, then a student-run<br />

NGO in the shantytowns of Caracas, Venezuela, the actual practical development really began in the<br />

1980s.<br />

93. See bancosol.combo/en/historia.htm.<br />

94. BRIGIT HELMS, ACCESS FOR ALL: BUILDING INCLUSIVE FINANCIAL SYSTEMS 9 (2006).<br />

95. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 807 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

formal financial services in Latin America. 96 Even in Chile, which has one of the<br />

most developed financial markets of the continent, only large and well-established<br />

firms have access to the range of financial instruments available. 97<br />

The large number of excluded people in Latin America will gain access only if<br />

financial services for low-income people are integrated into all three levels of the<br />

financial system: micro (financial service providers), meso (support services and<br />

infrastructure), and macro (legislation, regulation, and supervision). 98 Therefore, it<br />

will be necessary to coordinate public and private reforms in order to enhance the<br />

equality and access to financial systems.<br />

First, it is important to understand client demand and to translate this "into<br />

high-quality, affordable, and convenient financial services offered by a range of<br />

providers." 99 Today, microfinance is about building sound domestic financial<br />

intermediaries that can provide services to low-income clients on a permanent basis.<br />

Sustainability ensures that low-income clients have permanent access to services." °<br />

Second, to ensure sustainability, it is necessary to have a strong financial<br />

infrastructure (the meso level), which includes a complex and varied set of<br />

procedures and instruments "consist[ing] of systems that allow for electronic<br />

payments and service providers, such as auditors, raters, consulting services,<br />

information and point-of-sale technology vendors, specialized technical support, and<br />

professional associations." ' ' 1 "Accurate, standardized, and comparable information<br />

on financial performance is imperative for integrating microfinance into the financial<br />

system."' ' Finally, the government (the macro level) needs to offer a policy<br />

environment that allows competitive and diverse financial service providers to<br />

flourish. The key actions for governments are maintaining macroeconomic stability,<br />

avoiding interest rate caps, and refraining from distorting the market with<br />

unsustainable, subsidized, and high-delinquency loan programs. Governments can<br />

also adjust banking-sector regulation and supervision to facilitate microfinancing<br />

while also protecting low-income people's deposits. "Governments can further<br />

support financial services . . . by improving the legal framework for contract<br />

enforcement and collateral rights, ensuring practically and legally feasible systems of<br />

land titling, and ensuring that tax systems do not discriminate against different types<br />

of institutions engaged in microfinance." 3<br />

96. See Alvaro Ramfrez, The Microfinance Experience in Latin America and the Caribbean 5 (2004).<br />

available<br />

at<br />

http://www.ruralfinance.org/servlet/BinaryDownloaderServlet?filename=1126101177627_Microfinance-ex<br />

perience-inLAC.pdf.<br />

97. See Sophie Sirtaine, Access to Finance by Chilean Corporations 3,89 (World Bank Policy<br />

Research, Working Paper No. 3845, 2006), available at http://ideas.repec.org/p/wbk/wbrwps/3845.html.<br />

98. See HELMS, supra note 94, at 13-14.<br />

99. Id. at 140.<br />

100. Id. at 56.<br />

101. Id. at 140.<br />

102. Id. at 73.<br />

103. Id. at 92.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 808 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 809<br />

3. The Regulatory Reform<br />

"[T]he pressure for regulatory reform has been building on several fronts in<br />

[Latin America] since 1995."" Such pressure has led some countries in the region to<br />

create new types of financial institutions, precisely for the purpose of enabling<br />

nonprofit foundations to transform into financial intermediaries. 9<br />

Bolivia, for example, has a special law governing private financial funds or<br />

Fondos Financieros Privados (FFPs) that permits NGOs to become specialized<br />

financial institutions.' As of April 2005, the minimum capital for these NGOs<br />

required was only $1 million, while the minimum capital required for banks was $3<br />

million. 7 Like banks, FFPs are subject to prudential supervision and are monitored<br />

by the Banking Superintendency."' "The Superintendency requires all deposittaking<br />

institutions (including FFPs) to submit their financial statements on a daily<br />

basis, an administrative burden that may discourage FFPs from entering into more<br />

°9<br />

remote rural areas with weak telecommunications infrastructure.'<br />

There are two situations in which it may be appropriate to create a new<br />

type of institution to facilitate the transformation of nonprofit microcredit<br />

foundations into licensed and supervised financial intermediaries. First, if<br />

the minimum capital requirement for existing institutional forms . . . is<br />

very high it could prevent . I . mature and well-managed foundations from<br />

entering the formal financial system. Second, if the existing institutional<br />

form that has the lower minimum capital requirement . . . is severely<br />

limited in the type of operations it can carry out-particularly in the area<br />

of savings mobilization -then it may simply be an unattractive form of<br />

institution for those microcredit foundations that want to enter the formal<br />

financial system." °<br />

In some Latin America countries, "[t]he bad reputation of finance companies<br />

has sometimes been mentioned as a reason to create a new institutional form for<br />

non-profit foundations that want to transform into formal financial<br />

intermediaries.""'<br />

Creating new institutions for microfinance, even when well-justified and<br />

structured, is not enough to provide a regulatory framework for microfinance. The<br />

first and perhaps most important step to this end is to design appropriate regulations<br />

for microlending as such, in which the regulation "should be guided by three<br />

principles: flexibility, simplicity, and automaticity-flexibility in interest rates,<br />

collateral and internal credit processes; simplicity in client documentation, loan<br />

delinquency and recuperation of collateral; and automaticity in portfolio<br />

104. Tor Jansson, Microfinance Regulation Sweeping Latin America, MICROENTERPRISE DEV. REV.<br />

(Inter-American Development Bank), Aug. 2002, at 4, available at<br />

http://www.esglobal.com/pdf/PrivateCapitalforMicrofinanceHowtoTurn.pdf.<br />

105. Id.<br />

106. See HELMS, supra note 94, at 88, Box 5.6.<br />

107. Id.<br />

108. Id.<br />

109. Id.<br />

110. See Jansson, supra note 104. at 6.<br />

Ill. ld. at 6.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 809 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

classification, loan loss provisions and write-offs."". In conjunction, such "basic rules<br />

provide room for innovation, lower the regulatory costs of compliance and subject<br />

microlending to a strict recognition of revenues, expenses and risks."" ' 3<br />

Finally, although the regulatory framework is relevant, it constitutes only part<br />

of the story. The remaining part is supervision. "Since most of the regulatory<br />

initiatives are still quite recent (apart from Bolivia and Peru), supervisory authorities<br />

have not yet developed effective processes, tools and practices of supervision.""1 4<br />

"Ineffective supervision may be worse than none at all, because poor (and other)<br />

clients could be lulled into a false sense of security."" ' 5 "Achieving the proper mix of<br />

regulations and supervisory practices that foster competitive and sound<br />

microfinance" is the key, and it "will require a sustained commitment on the part of<br />

supervisory authorities."" 6<br />

Developing countries that are pursuing reforms to improve microfinance need<br />

to analyze all levels of the financial system, avoid distortion in other areas, and<br />

maintain the stability of the financial system as a whole.<br />

Importantly, the private sector should be brought to the table to participate in<br />

the microfinance process, seeing such participation as a commercial opportunity, and<br />

not as a money-loser or subsidized competition. The government, in turn, should<br />

foster competition and facilitate chartering of financial institutions specialized in<br />

lower-income segments of the population.<br />

B. An Example of Non-Regulatory Public-Private Initiative: The Case of South<br />

Africa<br />

South Africa, as a developing country, faces the general challenge of providing<br />

basic financial services to the poor. Specifically, the country is searching for ways to<br />

reduce the entrenched inequality of incomes, economic opportunities, and access to<br />

services left over from years of apartheid. Ironically, apartheid did leave South<br />

Africa with a developed banking system that served the dominating white<br />

population." 7 In the author's view, the "trick" is how to bring this banking sector<br />

into the developmental agenda of the country. With over half of the South African<br />

population living on $2 per day or less, it is imperative that the major financial<br />

institutions help redress the historically weak system of services for lower-income<br />

people.<br />

Facing impending regulation (i.e., a community reinvestment-type of legislation<br />

similar to that in the United <strong>State</strong>s), the South African financial sector recently has<br />

responded to this demand for the expansion of access to financial services to a<br />

broader segment of the population in the form of the Financial Sector Charter (the<br />

Charter). This negotiated document was adopted by the financial sector in October<br />

112. Id. at 8.<br />

113. Id.<br />

114. Id.<br />

115. See HELMS, supra note 94, at 87.<br />

116. See Jansson, supra note 104, at 8.<br />

117. See generally Tito Mboweni, Governor, South African Reserve Bank, Address at the Year End<br />

Media Cocktail Function, The South African Banking Sector: An Overview of the Past 10 Years 1 (Dec.<br />

14, 2004), available at http://www.bis.org/review/r041231f.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 810 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 811<br />

2003 and brought into effect on January 1, 2004."' The Charter represents an<br />

important private sector response to the broader challenges of transformation<br />

within, and transformation initiatives by, the financial sector.<br />

1. Background<br />

As mentioned above, South Africa has a well-developed and highly<br />

sophisticated formal banking system." 9 At the end of 2004, there were thirty-eight<br />

registered banks in South Africa.12 For historical reasons, a large proportion of the<br />

South African population has not been adequately served by the formal banking<br />

system.21 Mainly the poorest sectors of the population and rural areas have fallen<br />

outside of the net of the services provided by the formal banking system.' 22 Prior to<br />

the adoption of the Charter, the major banks were pressured to extend financial<br />

services-including credit for low-income housing to the poorest sectors of the South<br />

African population-and to desist from discriminatory lending practices. However,<br />

the government's response to the challenge of expanding access to financial services<br />

and access to housing finance for low income households has, from an early stage,<br />

been characterized by the search for constructive partnerships between the private<br />

sector and the public sector. The state would take measures to encourage the<br />

resumption of payments for goods and services, reinstating the rule of law, whereas<br />

the private sector would support the government in its efforts to bring about<br />

financial stability. In pursuing the goal of partnership with the private sector, it<br />

would seem as though there has been an almost studious avoidance of prescription<br />

to the private sector while at the same time maintaining subtle and overt pressure on<br />

the private sector lending institutions to participate more meaningfully in the<br />

transformation process. Two major legislative acts, the Home Loan and Mortgage<br />

Disclosure Act 23 and the draft Community Reinvestment (Housing) Bill of 2002, 2'<br />

'<br />

were developed by the Government but never actually implemented. This failure to<br />

implement legislation further reinforces the notion that the Government preferred<br />

to operate within a collaborative, as opposed to a prescriptive, framework with the<br />

financial sector.<br />

2. Responding to the Challenge: The Financial Sector Charter<br />

The Charter identifies a number of challenges facing the Sector, primarily the<br />

Sector's "inadequate" response to the increasing demand for access to financial<br />

118. The Financial Sector Charter, Jan. 1, 2004 (Financial Sector Charter), available at<br />

http://www.treasury.gov.za/press/other/2003101701.pdf.<br />

119. Gill Marcus, An Approach to the Consideration of Bank Merger Issues by Regulators: A South<br />

African Case, 4 BIS PAPERS 133 (2001), available at http://www.bis.org/publ/bispap04o.pdf.<br />

120. Tito Mboweni, supra note 117.<br />

121. Black Economic Empowerment Commission, BEECom Report 19 (2001), available at<br />

http://www.capegateway.gov.za/Text/2004/5/beecomreport.pdf.<br />

122. Id.; see also Marcus, supra note 119.<br />

123. Home Loan and Mortgage Disclosure Act 63 of 2000.<br />

124. Draft Community Reinvestment (Housing) Bill, 20002, Gazette 23423, Notice 747 (May 17,<br />

2002).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 811 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

services.' 2 ' The expansion of access to financial services is seen as "fundamental to<br />

[Black Economic Empowerment] BEE and to the development of the economy as a<br />

whole." '26 The broad commitment assumed in paragraph 8 of the Charter is to<br />

"increase effective access to first-order retail financial services to a greater segment<br />

of the population, within LSM 1-5. '' 127<br />

It is important to understand the two key concepts-"effective access" and<br />

"first order financial resources"-used in the Charter. The concept of "effective<br />

access" as utilized in the Charter has five dimensions: 1) Financial service<br />

infrastructure must be located within 20 kilometers of potential users; 2) The range<br />

of products must be sufficiently diverse; 3) The products must be offered nondiscriminatorily;<br />

4) The products offered must be appropriate and affordably priced;<br />

and 5) The products must be structured and described in an way that is easily<br />

accessible .<br />

"First-order retail financial services" as defined in the Charter include: 1)<br />

Transaction products and services, which serve the function of day-to-day purposes;<br />

2) Savings products and services, which serve the function of providing "a basic and<br />

secure means of accumulating funds over time"; 3) Credit for low-income housing;, 2<br />

and 4) Insurance products and services, which provide a cushion against defined first<br />

order basic risks. 130<br />

These provisions, and indeed the Charter as a whole, effectively depict the<br />

process of forming a constructive partnership between the Government and the<br />

private sector to meet the challenges of transformation.<br />

Additionally, the broad Charter commitment referred to above is made more<br />

concrete by a set of specific undertakings which can broadly be divided into two<br />

categories: those whose implementation is sector-centric in that the responsibility for<br />

their implementation rests solely with the Sector ("sector-centric undertakings"),<br />

and those whose implementation depends on negotiated arrangements reached with<br />

the Government and other actors ("collaborative undertaking"). Furthermore, the<br />

Charter parties undertake to establish, in collaboration with the Government, a<br />

monitoring and review mechanism "for the ongoing evaluation and review of the<br />

3<br />

impact of [the financial sector's initiatives] on access.'' This strengthens the notion<br />

of a partnership between the sector and the Government.<br />

3. Implementation Mechanisms<br />

An independent council with a broad mandate to oversee the implementation<br />

of the Charter is to be established.' 32 The Charter Council is required to undertake<br />

125. See Financial Sector Charter, supra note 118.<br />

126. Id. para. 8.1.<br />

127. Id. para. 8.3. LSM 1-5 refers to the Living Standards Measure designed by the South African<br />

Advertising Research Foundation; see generally http://www.saarf.co.za.<br />

128. See The Financial Sector Charter, supra note 118, para. 2.22.<br />

129. It should be noted that low-income housing in the context of first order financial services is<br />

aimed at households with a stable income of at least R$500 per month but below R$7500 per month. Id.<br />

paras. 2.27.3, 2.34.3.<br />

130. See id. para. 2.27 (examples of the first order risks mentioned are death and associated funeral<br />

costs, household insurance, and health insurance).<br />

131. Id. para. 8.6.<br />

132. Id. para. 15.1.1.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 812 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 813<br />

periodic reviews of the implementation of the Charter and is empowered to make<br />

decisions regarding the implementation of the Charter in its second term (2009-<br />

2014).' 33 The Charter Council is to be comprised of industry association<br />

representatives and other interested parties.1 4 Government representatives and<br />

other interest groups are among the "other" interest groups to be represented on the<br />

Charter Council. The Charter Council is specifically required to "fairly reflect the<br />

interests of all the financial institutions," suggesting that there was a concern that the<br />

independent body might undermine such interests. 9<br />

The decision-making mechanism in the Charter Council is consensus. This may<br />

be a mechanism for ensuring that the interests of financial institutions are not<br />

undermined in the Charter Council. It seems however that consensus is the primary,<br />

but not exclusive, mode of decision making within the Charter Council. An absolute<br />

consensus requirement would imply the possibility of institutional paralysis in<br />

circumstances where the Charter Council fails to reach consensus, especially on<br />

matters of importance. The Charter states that a dispute breaking mechanism will<br />

be agreed upon within the Charter Council, including the possibility of arbitration or<br />

mediation. 136 This suggests that it might be possible to have definitive outcomes on<br />

contentious issues arising out of the deliberations of the Charter Council, lessening<br />

the institutional implications of the consensus requirement.<br />

The Charter requires each financial institution to report its progress in<br />

implementing the provisions to the Charter Council on an annual basis.' 37 Financial<br />

institutions are required to publish an annual report for general information.' 38 This<br />

annual report is to include an audited scorecard and an account of the progress that<br />

the institution has made in discharging the unquantified responsibilities set out in the<br />

Charter. 9<br />

Although the Charter is non-binding in a hard, formal sense as it sets<br />

aspirational goals and standards of conduct, this does not undermine its importance.<br />

The primary value of the Charter lies in the voluntary assumption, by private parties,<br />

of part of the responsibility for making transformation work within a framework of<br />

collaboration and partnership with the public sector. The Charter parties have<br />

already begun to implement some of the provisions of the Charter relating to the<br />

expansion of financial services to low and moderate income households. In recent<br />

times some of the major banks have begun to open operating units in townships and<br />

remote rural areas.' 0 An important development in this regard was the creation and<br />

133. See id. paras. 15.1.1.,4.3.<br />

134. The industry associations that were involved in the formulation and adoption of the Charter were<br />

the Association of Black Securities and Investment Professionals (mandated by the Black Business<br />

Council), Banking Council of South Africa, Association of Collective Investments, Bond Exchange of<br />

South Africa, Foreign Bankers Association of South Africa, Institution of Retirement Funds, Life Offices'<br />

Association of South Africa, South African Insurers Association, Investment Managers Association of<br />

South Africa, JSE Securities Exchange South Africa, South African Reinsurance Offices' Association,<br />

South African Insurers Association.<br />

135. See The Financial Sector Charter, supra note 118, para. 15.1.1.<br />

136. Id.<br />

137. Seeid. para. 15.2.1.<br />

138. Id. para 15.2.2.<br />

139. See id. para. 15.2.4.<br />

140. John Reed, SA Takes Banks to the Townships: Banks are Responding to <strong>Law</strong>s at Correcting<br />

South Africa's Racially Skewed Financial Sector, FIN. TIMES, Oct. 12, 2004.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 813 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

launch, on October 25, 2004, of the Mzansi Account by the major banks together<br />

with Postbank (a government institution). The Mzansi Account is designed<br />

specifically to meet the needs of previously ignored communities.'' The first set of<br />

quantitative data on the Mzansi Account suggests that that it is a runaway success."'<br />

According to the data, as of February 2005, over half a million Mzansi Accounts had<br />

been opened.' Furthermore, an average of six thousand accounts was being opened<br />

across the country each day.'"<br />

In sum, the adoption of the Charter and the apparent impetus of the Sector to<br />

collaborate with the Government in implementing the Charter's provisions vindicate<br />

the Government's partnership-seeking approach in dealing with the banking sector<br />

to achieve the extension of financial services and housing finance to low to moderate<br />

income borrowers/depositors. The financial sector's initiatives in response to the<br />

Charter have proven successful thus far and indicate a real potential for the<br />

meaningful extension of financial services.<br />

V. CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS: THE NEED FOR A SUITABLE<br />

LEGAL-INSTITUTIONAL INFRASTRUCTURE AND POLICY<br />

REORIENTATION<br />

The world of the IFIs and Regional Financial Institutions (RFIs) has<br />

historically been a world of economists, a large portion of whom are<br />

macroeconomists, while law and lawyers traditionally have played a very minimal<br />

role. But, during the 1990s, the IFIs/RFIs came to learn and appreciate the<br />

importance of the legal-institutional infrastructure of a country in supporting the<br />

domestic financial system by: 1) establishing the requisite institutional and<br />

administrative capacities; 2) developing the desired supporting linkages between the<br />

public and private sectors; 3) putting in place clear rights, responsibilities, and<br />

liabilities of parties in a transaction; 4) maintaining the appropriate incentives and<br />

adequate information that espouse market forces; and 5) providing adequate and<br />

fair means to enforce legal obligations and claims effectively.<br />

This author recognizes that for over a decade, institutions such as the World<br />

Bank and the IMF have expended considerable efforts on "deepening" financial<br />

sector legal-institutional infrastructure reform in developing countries (e.g., as to the<br />

legal aspects focusing on the importance of property and contract rights and<br />

remedies, secured transactions, corporate governance, and corporate and bank<br />

insolvency;... and as to the institutional aspects focusing on modern administrative,<br />

enforcement, and judicial bodies1 46 ). Such legal-institutional and infrastructural<br />

141. Media Release, The Banking Council of S. Afr., Mzansi will Put Full Service Banking within<br />

15KM of the Vast Majority of South Africans (Oct. 15, 2004), available at http://www.banking.org.za.<br />

142. Media Release, The Banking Council of S. Afr., The First Set of Data Shows Mzansi Hit the Spot<br />

(Feb. 9, 2005), available at<br />

http://www.banking.org.za/documents/2005/FEBRUARY/MzansiData_090205.asp.<br />

143. Id.<br />

144. Id.<br />

145. See, e .g., World Bank, Principles and Guidelines for Effective Insolvency and Creditor Rights<br />

Systems (April 2001), available at http://www.worldbank.org/ifa/Insolvency Principles and Guidelines April<br />

2001.pdf<br />

146. In the latter part of the 1990s and currently, the World Bank has been most active in the area of<br />

judicial reform.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 814 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 815<br />

reforms are indeed a prerequisite to a sound foundation for building a viable<br />

financial sector. However, these reforms fail to consider what a country wishes its<br />

financial system to embrace, the base of participants to include, or what policies,<br />

institutions, and additional legal infrastructure to implement in order to achieve<br />

these developmental objectives.<br />

For the legal system to achieve these objectives, key legislation needs to be put<br />

into place, i.e., at a minimum, modern contract, corporate, bankruptcy, private<br />

property, and commercial laws, as well as modern banking and investment securities<br />

laws (and even, most probably, a basic asset securitization law). These latter legal<br />

provisions specifically governing financial activities need to be rule-based and<br />

transparent while preserving a required degree of flexibility necessary to adapt to<br />

innovations and changing market conditions. The financial legislation/regulations<br />

should promulgate disclosure of information so as to enable market forces to<br />

discipline the activities of financial institutions and "market players." Clarity of<br />

entry and exit standards of financial institutions reduces uncertainty within the<br />

financial markets. A well-defined exit policy is especially imperative since this is the<br />

time when the market is likely to act rashly and to cause self-fulfilling bank runs."'<br />

In addition, administrative and judicial procedures need to be sufficiently clear<br />

and to be backed up with quality enforcement entailed to them. The problem for<br />

many emerging economies is the lack of any effective administration and<br />

enforcement. Thus, ensuring that enforcement is carried out extends the<br />

appropriate incentives for market participants to act normatively. Two specific<br />

priorities are seen as improving the enforcement of financial contracts: 1) Effective<br />

means to take possession of collateral exist; and 2) Revision and updating of legal<br />

codes are carried out to reflect new market realities.<br />

The lack of legal remedies in the case of non-compliance can paralyze the<br />

market and discourage foreigners from investing in emerging markets. The<br />

uncertainty surrounding the outcome of legal procedures and processes also inhibits<br />

the robustness of financial markets. 148<br />

Other key components for building modern international financial best<br />

practices/standards might include the twelve key standards set out by the Financial<br />

Stability Forum. ' 14<br />

9 All these reform components serve to strengthen and deepen the<br />

stability base of the preexisting financial sector, which is only representative of the<br />

top of the socioeconomic pyramid. However, they are not designed to broaden the<br />

financial sector base.<br />

As mentioned above, the G7/8 views the "robustness" of a financial system is<br />

an essential characteristic of a stable system. To promote this, the G10 Working<br />

Group has identified three crucial actions that should be taken by each country<br />

according to their specific situation:<br />

147. See Ernesto Aguirre, The World Bank-Bank Insolvency Regim and the Global Bank Insolvency<br />

Initiative (2003) (discussing bank insolvency principles), available at<br />

http://info.worldbank.org/etools/docs/library/83870/aguirre.pdf.<br />

148. Cf., John Hewko, Foreign Direct Investment: Does the Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Matter? (Carnegie<br />

Endowment for International Peace, Working Paper No. 26, 2002); Jeswald W. Salacuse, From Developing<br />

Countries to Emerging Markets: A Changing Role for <strong>Law</strong> in the Third World, 33 INT'L LAw. 875 (1999).<br />

149. See NORTON, supra note 11, ch. 2; but cf., FSF, Compendium of Standards, available at<br />

http://www.fsforum.org/compendium/about.html.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 815 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:789<br />

[1)] Creation of an institutional setting and financial infrastructure<br />

necessary for a sound credit culture and effective market functioning[;]...<br />

[2)] Promotion of the functioning of markets so that owners, directors,<br />

investors and other actual and potential stakeholders exercise adequate<br />

discipline over financial institutions[; and] . . . [3)] Creation of regulatory<br />

and supervisory arrangements that complement and support the operation<br />

of market discipline.'<br />

This would entail improving the infrastructural aspects of the financial system,<br />

namely, the legal and judicial framework, accounting and disclosure standards, and<br />

market structure. When viewed in this way, financial legal sector reform becomes a<br />

deep, complex, and long-term matrix of reform efforts, presenting truly awesome<br />

challenges for, and demands on, the IFI resources and personnel at a time when they<br />

are being pressured to react to ongoing, immediate financial crises."' Yet, the<br />

deepness of this reform process is not directed toward broadening the reform base to<br />

be more inclusive as to access or as to serving true developmental objectives.<br />

What is rightly asserted by Claessens and Perotti now seems self-evident for<br />

those who have been involved with financial sector reform: the relationships<br />

between inequality and finance seem to be becoming clearer at the beginning of the<br />

twenty-first century. Important research conducted so far has suggested that to<br />

reduce inequality, financial systems need to be broadened, not just deepened.<br />

"Financial reform will only reduce inequality . . . if it improves access to growth<br />

opportunities for more individuals. Reforms thus need to broaden, not just deepen<br />

financial systems." ' 2 Certainly, in logically and pragmatically following through on<br />

Sen's paradigm of "choice (freedom) and development," choice presupposes<br />

meaningful and effective "access.'. 53 Access, in turn, presupposes the existence of<br />

suitable supporting governmental policies and financial sector infrastructure, which<br />

presumes the presence of appropriate, supporting policies, institutions, legal<br />

infrastructure, and legal instruments.<br />

However, the need to broaden is not simply about creating greater access to the<br />

financial system for the currently disenfranchised population, but should also<br />

address broadening the financial system itself so that it is not structurally geared only<br />

to the elite economic, business, and social elements of a developing country's society.<br />

The financial system should also be systemically structured in terms of suitable<br />

development policy to provide appropriate institutions, laws, and instruments for<br />

accommodating the poor, low-income, and other excluded elements of the country's<br />

population. For instance, it becomes critical to identify the particular sectors of a<br />

society that need priority development (e.g., agriculture, small business, housing,<br />

social safety net components, etc.), to assess the extent the existing financial sector<br />

and institutions might be better utilized in furthering such developmental objectives,<br />

and to determine what new institutions, laws, regulations, and instruments might be<br />

required. To achieve all this in a coherent, sequenced, and long-term sustainable<br />

150. Working Party on Financial Stability in Emerging Market Economies, Financial Stability in<br />

Emerging Economies, 3-4 (Apr. 1997).<br />

151. See, e.g., early discussion of the problems in EMERGING FINANCIAL MARKETS AND THE ROLE<br />

OF INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL ORGANIZATIONS (Joseph J. Norton & Mads Andenas eds., 1996).<br />

152. Stijn Claessens & Enrico Perotti, The Links Between Finance and Inequality: Channels and<br />

Evidence 1 (World Bank, Background Paper for the 2006 World Development Report, 2005).<br />

153. See generally AMARTYA SEN, DEVELOPMENT As FREEDOM (2000).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 816 2006-2007


2007 BANKING LAW REFORM AND USERS-CONSUMERS IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 817<br />

manner is indeed an enormous challenge for any country and for the supporting<br />

IFIs/RFIs. But, without having a financial system that is relevant to a country's<br />

developmental stage and objectives, and designed to bring in and to serve the<br />

excluded in meaningful ways, a country's financial system cannot effectively<br />

contribute to optimum, meaningful, and sustainable socioeconomic development.<br />

Nor can such a system provide a broad, stable platform for achieving stability with<br />

robust and sustained growth in the financial sector.<br />

As indicated in the first paragraph of this Article, this author originally had<br />

intended to address in detail the types of protection banking and financial sector<br />

users-consumers in developing countries might require, until it became apparent that<br />

the more fundamental need was the creation of a suitable user-consumer base, which<br />

is currently lacking in developing countries. Should there also be consumer<br />

protection in the financial sector of developing economies? Certainly, the answer<br />

must be yes. In creating greater access to the financial sector, consumer protection<br />

should be achieved in an equitable manner, and part of this equity needs to be the<br />

assurance that both new users-consumers and those not yet included are fairly<br />

treated and protected from predatory, overreaching, and abusive practices (formal<br />

and informal). The provision of such protection should not be viewed as an<br />

afterthought or as a subsequent level of reform, but should be an integral and<br />

contemporaneous part of the access-equity financial sector reform agenda.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 817 2006-2007


HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 818 2006-2007


Group Insolvencies - Some Thoughts About<br />

New Approaches<br />

CHRISTOPH G. PAULUS*<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. G ENERAL O BSERVATIONS ................................................................................. 819<br />

II. INCREASE OF E FFICIENCY .................................................................................. 820<br />

III. THE EUROPEAN D EVELOPMENT ....................................................................... 821<br />

IV . FURTHER CONSIDERATIONS .............................................................................. 825<br />

I. GENERAL OBSERVATIONS<br />

It is remarkable that one phenomenon within insolvency law has caught<br />

relatively little attention in the past among academics and legislators when put in<br />

relation to its practical importance and to the dramatically increased attention<br />

towards insolvency law in general. This increase reaches back roughly ten years-it<br />

began when the bubble of the so called tiger states' economies in East Asia began to<br />

burst, spread to Japan and Russia, and came finally to a stand-still in Brazil. In those<br />

days, in the middle of the 90s of the last century the globe came irritatingly close to a<br />

world economy crisis. The G-7 <strong>State</strong>s reacted and established the Financial Stability<br />

Forum whose task was-and still is-to build up safeguards against a repetition of<br />

such a risky development. This Forum spotted twelve topics that it sees as critical<br />

for the financial stability of an economy-one of them being insolvency law.' It<br />

entrusted its observation and assessment to the World Bank, which in turn is<br />

supported by the United Nations Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong><br />

(UNCITRAL) with respect to insolvency laws' implementation. 2<br />

. Christoph G. Paulus is Professor of <strong>Law</strong> at the Humboldt University in Berlin. He is member of the<br />

International Insolvency Institute, the American College of Bankruptcy, and the International Association<br />

of Procedural <strong>Law</strong>, and has also worked as a Consultant to both the International Monetary Fund and the<br />

World Bank. He wishes to express his deep gratitude to Professor Jay Westbrook, who read through the<br />

draft of the manuscript and gave invaluable comments.<br />

1. See generally Christoph G. Paulus, The Global Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> and the Role of Multinational<br />

Institutions, BROOK. J. INT'L L. (forthcoming 2007).<br />

2. See Financial Stability Forum, 12 Key Standards for Sound Financial Systems,<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 819 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:819<br />

However, the increased importance of insolvency laws is best documented<br />

through the published papers of the three big Multilaterals, which give legislators<br />

more or less detailed advice on how to draft a modern and effective insolvency law.<br />

The International Monetary Fund (IMF) was the first to publish in 1999, 3 followed<br />

by the World Bank in 2001,' and finally by UNCITRAL 5 in 2004. During this time<br />

the American <strong>Law</strong> Institute was tackling how to better coordinate cross-border<br />

insolvencies resulting from an increased number of bankruptcies where creditors and<br />

assets were located in more than one North American Free Trade Agreement<br />

(NAFTA) country. 6 Within those five years insolvency law mutated from an area of<br />

law reserved for centuries to a rather isolated circle of specialists, to one of practical<br />

global importance.<br />

Irrespective of this development, astonishingly little work was put into<br />

deliberations about how to deal with the insolvency of not only a single legal entity<br />

but with that of a group of such entities as a whole. This neglect is reflected in the<br />

previously mentioned papers-the UNCITRAL Legislative Guide is the only one<br />

that even touches on this topic, and still devotes only a chapter to it. The substance<br />

of this chapter is to bring attention to the important role this issue plays in practice,<br />

and to illustrate the need for further consideration and research. Such consideration<br />

is being undertaken by a Working Group, which has recently (Dec. 2006) been<br />

established. It is generally well known that the insolvency of a company, which is a<br />

member of a group of companies, will often initiate a domino effect, leading to the<br />

subsequent downfall of the other group members. The consequence is that there are<br />

as many insolvent companies (and insolvency proceedings) as there are group<br />

members; the rule is "one company, one insolvency, one proceeding." This<br />

phenomenon is particularly prevalent when cross-border issues are at stake. It is<br />

therefore not surprising that, at least in continental Europe, the need and necessity<br />

for intensified deliberations has been recognized in the wake of the European<br />

Insolvency Regulation enactment in mid-2002.<br />

II.<br />

INCREASE OF EFFICIENCY<br />

Before describing this development, it might be appropriate to pause for a<br />

moment and to observe the factual and legal situation in the case of multiple<br />

insolvencies. What has been a more or less coherent economic unit' becomes, so to<br />

http://www.fsforum.org/compendium/key-standards for -sound financial-system.html.<br />

3. See International Monetary Fund, Modern & Effective Insolvency Proceedings (1999), available at<br />

http://www.intemationalmonetaryfund.com/external/pubs/ft/orderly/index.htm.<br />

4. See The World Bank, Principles for Insolvency and Creditor Rights Systems 1 (Dec. 21, 2005),<br />

available<br />

at<br />

http://web.worldbank.org[WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/LAWANDJUSTICE/GILD/0,,contentMDK:2<br />

0774193-pagePK:64065425-piPK:162156-theSitePK:215006,00.html. The World Bank's original Principles<br />

were developed in 2001 in response to the financial crises in emerging markets in the late 1990s. In 2005,<br />

the Principles were thoroughly reviewed and revised. See id., at 1-3.<br />

5. See UNCITRAL, 2004 UNCITRAL Legislative Guide on Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> (June 25, 2004),<br />

www.uncitral.org/uncitral/en/uncitral-texts/insolvency/2004Guide.html.<br />

6. See generally Lance Liebman, Forward to AM. LAW INST., PRINCIPLES OF COOPERATION AMONG<br />

THE NAFTA COUNTRIES xv, xv- xvii (2003) (noting that the bankruptcy systems of NAFTA countries-<br />

Canada, Mexico, and the United <strong>State</strong>s-were the primary focus of the ALI's PRINCIPLES).<br />

7. To be sure, what is presented here is somewhat simplified, as the appearances of groups are<br />

manifold. See GERARD HERTIG & HIDEKI KANDA, Creditor Protection, in THE ANATOMY-OF<br />

CORPORATE LAW 71, 75 (Renier R. Kraakman et al. eds., 2004) (for an analysis of the intricacies and<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 820 2006-2007


2007 GROUP INSOLVENCIES - SOME THOUGHTS ABOUT NEW APPROACHES 821<br />

speak, a pile of shards-each separate legal entity is subject to its own insolvency<br />

proceeding as the decision to open a proceeding for each entity is determined<br />

separate and independent of the others. 8 The consequence is that there are many<br />

insolvency administrators to be appointed, many creditors' assemblies and<br />

committees to be conducted, and many investigations to be initiated into potential<br />

pre-proceeding transactions of the debtor-to the detriment of the creditors as well<br />

as into potential violations of directors' duties. This is only a brief overview of the<br />

activities to be initiated after the economic and legal breakdown of the group<br />

entities; it makes sufficiently clear that the real topic behind any considerations<br />

about the law of group insolvencies is the desire and need for greater efficiency.<br />

Like the parallel set of intricacies in the field of cross-border insolvency law where<br />

the universality principle is gaining more and more ground internationally due to its<br />

greater efficiency prospect, one should approach the intricacies of a group insolvency<br />

law, too, from the perspective of increased efficiency.<br />

A closer look at this statement-as convincing as it might appear at first<br />

glance-reveals that there are some traps better avoided at the outset. One has to<br />

ask, namely, what is meant by "greater efficiency?" This question touches on the<br />

fact that not all insolvency laws in this world are premised on the same policy<br />

objectives. Thus, some laws declare it as their highest priority to achieve the best<br />

possible satisfaction of the creditors. Some say almost the contrary-namely to give<br />

the debtor the chance of a fresh start, or to foster entrepreneurialship in general.<br />

Still others view efficiency as preserving the work place, the integrity of the<br />

economic unit, or ensuring payment of certain creditors in that very state. Efficiency<br />

under these diverse circumstances thus comes to have different meanings, which<br />

must be kept in mind for possible solutions to the problem of group insolvencies. As<br />

a working hypothesis, I define efficiency in this text as asset maximization by<br />

preserving the debtor companies to the utmost while obtaining the best possible<br />

satisfaction of the creditors. I emphasize this hypothesis will be fine-tuned in the<br />

future, and should be treated as a hypothesis in its infant stage of development.<br />

III. THE EUROPEAN DEVELOPMENT<br />

It is fair to say that the English administrators and courts have taught the<br />

continent a lesson in how to interpret the written law. The European Insolvency<br />

Regulation is built on the concept of what is usually called "modified universality."<br />

Under such a regime, an insolvency proceeding opened in one of the member states<br />

is automatically recognized in all other member states. As a general rule, the<br />

insolvency law of the opening state-the so called lex concursus-is to be applied in<br />

all other member states. This universalistic approach, extending to the territory of<br />

twenty-five member states, is subject to some exceptions. 9 The most important one<br />

complexities of corporate groups).<br />

8. Henry Peter describes this phenomenon as privileging "form over substance." Cf Henry Peter,<br />

Insolvency in a Group of Companies, Substantive and Procedural Consolidation: When and How?, in THE<br />

CHALLENGES OF INSOLVENCY LAW REFORM IN THE 21' CENTURY 199 (Henry Peter et al. eds., 2006).<br />

9. For a general discussion of the European Insolvency Regulation (EIR), see CHRISTOPH G.<br />

PAULUS, EUROPAISCHE INSOLVENZVERORDNUNG-KOMMENTAR 57 ff. (2002); GABRIEL MOSS, IAN<br />

FLETCHER, & STUART ISAACS, THE EC REGULATION ON INSOLVENCY PROCEEDINGS 155 (2002); and<br />

Miguel Virg6s & Francisco Garcimartfn, The Normative Model, in THE EUROPEAN INSOLVENCY<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 821 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:819<br />

in the present context is the possibility to have secondary proceedings opened in<br />

every member state where the debtor has an establishment. The effect of this<br />

insolvency proceeding, however, is restricted to this member state, for it follows the<br />

territoriality principle.<br />

This distinction between the types of proceedings necessitates a rule according<br />

to which one proceeding is the main one and the other the secondary one. For the<br />

latter, the "establishment" is decisive, whereas the main proceeding is to be opened<br />

pursuant to Article 3 paragraph 1 of the European Insolvency Regulation (EIR) in<br />

the member state where the debtor has its "centre of main interests." This standard<br />

was adopted by the drafters of the UNCITRAL model law on cross-border<br />

insolvencies, turning the standard's designation into something of a global standard."<br />

Many in Europe thought that this is quite a precise definition requiring not<br />

much interpretation"-particularly when seen in combination with the further rule<br />

that this centre is to be presumed where the company has its registered seat, unless<br />

proven to the contrary." By contrast, the professionals from the Island declared,<br />

occasionally in a superficial and a bit far-fetched manner, the centre of a group<br />

subsidiary to be located at the seat of the mother company when and if it exercised<br />

the "head office functions." The English courts generally accepted this<br />

interpretation so that an astonishing number of cross-border group insolvency<br />

proceedings were opened in England. Needless to say, the reaction in the rest of<br />

Europe was rather harsh, even though (or better perhaps because of) there was not<br />

much maneuvering available due to the automatic recognition rule in the<br />

Regulation. However, after some grumbling, the lawyers on the continent followed<br />

this approach and declared the location of the mother company as the centre of main<br />

interest for the mother's subsidiaries. Courts in Italy, 3 Germany, 4 Hungary,' 5 and<br />

most recently France 16 have followed this line of argument and decided accordingly.<br />

REGULATION: LAW AND PRACTICE 11, 11-14 (2004). As to possible and desirable improvements, see<br />

Gabriel Moss & Christoph G. Paulus, The European Insolvency Regulation - The Case for Urgent Reform,<br />

19 INSOLV. INT. 1, 1 (2006).<br />

10. For a discussion of this term and the problems created thereby, see Jay Westbrook, Locating the<br />

Eye of the Financial Storm, BROOK. J. INT'L L. (forthcoming 2007); Gabriel Moss, Group Insolvency -<br />

Choice of Forum and <strong>Law</strong>: The European Experience Under the Influence of English Pragmatism, BROOK.<br />

J. INT'L L. (forthcoming 2007).<br />

11. This formulation is modeled after Section 3.1 of the German Insolvency Ordinance, which reads:<br />

The insolvency court in whose district the debtor has his usual venue shall have exclusive local<br />

jurisdiction. If the centre of the debtor's self-employed business activity is located elsewhere,<br />

the insolvency court in whose district such place is located shall have exclusive jurisdiction.<br />

Insolvenzordnung [Insolvency Statute], Oct. 5, 1994 I.S. 2866, § 3.1 (F.R.G.). It is obvious that this<br />

determination of the competent court causes few (if any) problems within one and the same jurisdiction.<br />

12. Some authors argue that this presumption should become the unrebuttable rule. See, e.g., Horst<br />

Eidenmuiller, Free Choice in International Company Insolvency <strong>Law</strong> in Europe, 6 EUR. Bus. ORG. L. REV.<br />

423 (2005).<br />

13. See Cecilia Carrara, The Parmalat Case, 70 RABELS ZEITSCHRIFr FOR AUSLANDISCHES UND<br />

INTERNATIONALS PRIVATRECHT [F.R.G.] 538 (2006).<br />

14. See District Court of Munich, May 4, 2004, available at<br />

http://ww9184.wb09.de/eirdatabase/adminlbilder eir/123-1_EMTEC.pdf.<br />

15. See Commercial Court of Nanterre, Feb. 15, 2006, available at<br />

http://ww9184.wb9.de/eirdatabase/admin/bilder-eir/47-1-PARMALAT%20Hungary-Slovakia.pdf.<br />

16. See Fejer, June 14, 2004, available at http://ww9184.wb09.de/eirdatabase/admin/bildereir/123-<br />

1_EMTEC.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 822 2006-2007


2007<br />

GROUP INSOLVENCIES - SOME THOUGHTS ABOUT NEW APPROACHES<br />

After all, the English approach was a step towards developing a group<br />

insolvency law, since now the group as a whole was in the hands of one administrator<br />

in one insolvency proceeding-a much more efficient way of handling the insolvency<br />

of a group than the one envisaged by the Regulation. Its approach is the<br />

aforementioned rule: "one company, one insolvency, one proceeding." Moreover,<br />

even if a subsidiary could be seen as an establishment which would justify the<br />

commencement of a secondary proceeding, EIR Art.3 par. 3(2) says that this<br />

proceeding has to be a liquidation proceeding from the outset, excluding from the<br />

outset the possibility of a reorganization of the group as a whole or even of coherent<br />

parts of it.<br />

What so far sounds as a success story of the English approach was confronted<br />

only a few months ago with serious irritations. The well-known Parmalat case 7<br />

opened the stage for a recent decision of the European Court of Justice (ECJ).<br />

Parmelat, the huge and world-wide acting group, had one affiliate in Dublin, Ireland.<br />

For tax purposes it was founded there under the name Eurofood; the company's task<br />

was to collect financial means for the group as a whole. Like all the other group<br />

related companies-and typically for the aforementioned domino effect-Eurofood<br />

also went into an insolvency proceeding; the question of which national law exactly<br />

governs this proceeding as lex concursus, however, gave rise to a dispute between<br />

the Irish and the Italian courts. The issue finally became settled by the court in<br />

Luxemburg. The chain of events started namely with a filing in Dublin which<br />

initiated a preliminary proceeding; the proceeding included some protective<br />

measures to the benefit of the creditors, with the peculiarity that, pursuant to Irish<br />

law, the date of filing shall be assumed as the date of the opening of the insolvency<br />

proceeding when and if the court later concludes that the filing requirements are met<br />

and that the company is in fact insolvent.<br />

However, before the Irish insolvency court came to this conclusion the relevant<br />

insolvency court in Parma had also opened the insolvency proceeding over<br />

Eurofood-with almost no delay. Eurofood, thus, had the dubious position to be<br />

subject to two mutually excluding insolvency regimes. After considering Advocate<br />

General Jacobs' opinion, 8 the ECJ decided May 2, 2006'" that the commencement of<br />

the Irish proceeding-irrespective of its preliminary nature and lack of an officially<br />

determined insolvency-was the earlier proceeding. Hence the Italian proceeding,<br />

according to the priority rule, was to be closed. 0<br />

This, however, is the decision given only in this particular case. Its reasoning<br />

leaves room for further interpretation. In its heavy reliance on the Regulation's<br />

Consideration No. 13 and its repetition in the Virg6s/Schmit report, the court<br />

emphasizes the need for the recognizability of the centre of main interests for third<br />

persons. They would, in the case at hand and under the given circumstances, find<br />

that centre in Ireland. The court offers additional explanations, one of which is that<br />

17. For a detailed description of this case, see Carrara, supra note 13, at 538.<br />

18. See Christoph Paulus, Professor Paulus on Advocate General Jacobs' Opinion in the Eurofood<br />

case, 70 GLOBAL TURNAROUND 10 (Nov. 2005), available at<br />

http://www.globalturnaround.com/article.php?issue-number=70.<br />

19. See generally Eurofood IFSC Lid, 2006 O.J. (C 341) 4, available at http://curia.europa.eu/jurisp/cgibin/form.pl?lang=en&Submit=Submit&alldocs=alldocs&docj=docj&docop=docop&docor=docor&dcj=<br />

docjo&numaff=&datefs=&datefe=&nomusuel=eurofood&domaine= &mots=&resmax=100.<br />

20. For a more detailed discussion of this decision, see Moss, supra note 10.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 823 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:819<br />

the "mind of management," or head office functions, might be acceptable in evident<br />

cases such as a mere letterbox company or the like.<br />

Taking into account that there is no definition of what constitutes the "centre of<br />

main interests," it is astonishing that the decision (as well as the Regulation and the<br />

report of M. Virg6s and E. Schmit) abstains from any explanation as to who<br />

constitutes "third persons." Depending on how one answer this question, however,<br />

great differences might result there from. Given the fact that the debtor company is<br />

a legally separate entity, the members of the board of directors, for instance, are<br />

"third persons," as are all employees. It is fair to assume that they regularly know<br />

about the group relationship-at least in most cases. But even further, creditors are<br />

"third persons"-at least the bigger ones (the Bank of America in the Eurofood<br />

case 2 ") do very well know about the group structure. They all do not matter,<br />

according to the ECJ judgment. The example of the mail box company given by the<br />

ECJ indicates the mailman's irrelevance. 22 We may have to conclude that the third<br />

persons are the judges. The decision states that "the mere fact that its economic<br />

choices are or can be controlled by a parent company in another Member <strong>State</strong> is<br />

not enough to rebut the presumption laid down by the Regulation." 23<br />

The previous statement suggests that, if additional facts had been added, the<br />

decision could have come out differently. 24 The letterbox company need not<br />

necessarily be taken as the only possible example-it is in fact an extreme case (note<br />

the decision's use of "in particular"). 5 To save the progress in group insolvency law<br />

which had been achieved in- Europe before the Eurofood decision, the search for<br />

additional facts is justified. I am convinced that the decision would have been<br />

decided differently if the name of the filing debtor had been Parmalat Finance<br />

Support and not Eurofood. Had Parmalat Finance Support filed, the company<br />

locale would be evident to the judges. The locale might also have been evident if the<br />

commercial advertisements for the company hinted towards the group to which the<br />

company belonged (i.e., member of the X group). Probably many more iterations<br />

might be thought of to justify this result which the ECJ-only on first sight-seems<br />

to exclude.<br />

In sum: the English interpretation has shown a better way to come to grips with<br />

insolvency proceedings in a group of companies versus the traditional way. The<br />

Eurofood decision is not necessarily a backdrop; the reasoning can be interpreted in<br />

a way that reconciles the two allegedly opposing old and new views. The "mere<br />

fact" that the mind of management is abroad does not suffice anymore; however, if<br />

objective, third parties deem that recognizable facts hint towards the adherence to a<br />

group, the parent company can be seen as the affiliate's centre of main interests. To<br />

be sure, this interpretation does nothing to provide a clearer rule than the existing<br />

one with its continuation of the "centre of main interests" language. 26 Improvements<br />

21. Note that the "driving force" behind the Eurofood case was a creditor that wanted to have the<br />

insolvency proceeding opened in Ireland. See Carrara, supra note 13.<br />

22. See Eurofood, supra note 19, para. 35.<br />

23. Id. para. 36.<br />

24 But see Christoph G. Paulus, The Aftermath of "Eurofood" - BenQ Holding B.V. and the<br />

Deficiencies of the ECJ Decision, 20 Insolvency Intelligence 2007, 85 et seq. (commenting a decision of the<br />

Amsterdam Arrondissement Court from Jan. 31, 2007).<br />

25. Id. para. 35.<br />

26. See Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook, Multinational Financial Distress: The Last Hurrah of Territorialism,<br />

41 TEx. INT'L L.J. 321, 332, 334 (book review) (rightly pointing out that the COMI approach is a generally<br />

well functioning "first step" that provides a "good, although not perfect, level of predictability and<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 824 2006-2007


2007 GROUP INSOLVENCIES - SOME THOUGHTS ABOUT NEW APPROACHES 825<br />

are possible and desirable-for example, by requiring a purely objective fact, rather<br />

than a "third party" subjective perception of the existence of an objective fact. It<br />

should be assumed, however, that the decision of the ECJ will have some impact on<br />

foreign jurisdictions such as the U.S., which also rely on the "centre of main<br />

interests" due to the influence insofar with the UNCITRAL Model <strong>Law</strong>. 27<br />

IV. FURTHER CONSIDERATIONS<br />

This Paper has thus far been more or less descriptive-i.e. reporting about facts<br />

and developments. These facts shall form the basis for further considerations about<br />

what appears to be feasible with respect to group insolvency law and what is<br />

desirable.<br />

However, before turning to further considerations, we should contemplate the<br />

justification of the traditional maxim "one company, one insolvency, one<br />

proceeding." The maxim has the enormous advantage of clarifying legal<br />

relationships-an advantage which brings us back as far as to ancient Roman law.<br />

From a bird's eye view, one of its greatest achievements is that it reduced the<br />

complexity of real life dramatically by constructing a parallel legal world which splits<br />

this very complexity more or less into relationships between two persons. This is<br />

roughly true for substantive law as well as procedural law; still today our basic legal<br />

instruments in private law are the debtor-creditor relationship and the plaintiffdefendant<br />

relationship. To be sure, we can add many more actors but that does not<br />

exclude that the basic legal denominator is such relationship between two persons.<br />

By sticking to this elementary rule, the traditional maxim offers the valuable clarity<br />

of designating the debtor and its creditors.<br />

Some scholars add another justification: the claim that the creditors' trust in<br />

legal realities must be respected; these scholars seem to indicate that the creditors<br />

have selected their debtor with deliberation and have thus acquired the right that the<br />

law must respect their decision for this particular debtor. However, a legal argument<br />

based upon trust alone is shaky. Its psychological undertone has, to the best of my<br />

knowledge, never really been examined-let alone tested. Additionally, is it not<br />

equally justifiable to state that the Bank of America, as Eurofood's main creditor,<br />

had more trust in the then-powerful Parmalat parent company than the new and<br />

quite dependent Eurofood? Therefore, this argument can at best be used for either<br />

side, limiting its persuasiveness.<br />

A third justification brings us back to more solid ground. The said clarity of a<br />

two-person relationship is well at place when the issue is who gets what from whom.<br />

In terms of insolvency law, this is when a liquidation proceeding is at stake in which<br />

the debtor's assets are sold piecemeal or as a whole to a third party (i.e. not to the<br />

creditors) so that the creditors receive at least their quota from their debtor's estate.<br />

If all companies in a group undergo this type of proceeding, it might be easier to<br />

liquidate all assets within just that recently opened proceeding that has been opened<br />

over the legal entity that is (or has been) owner of these assets. As a general rule, it<br />

is fair to assume that the sum of proceeds from each group member's piecemeal<br />

control.").<br />

27. 11 U.S.C. § 1302(4) (2007).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 825 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:819<br />

liquidation sales is about equal to the sum of proceeds from one collective<br />

liquidation sale.<br />

However, the advantage of transparency and clarity of two-person relationships is<br />

not as important when the sale of a going concern is at stake (whereby "going<br />

concern" in the present context means the added value of the group as a whole, or at<br />

least certain parts of it). A recent European example is the Collins & Aikman case<br />

which concerned some twenty-four companies in ten different member states of the<br />

EIR. 28 In a remarkable effort to keep the proceedings of over ten companies in<br />

different jurisdictions together, the court promised the local creditors the dividend<br />

(notably: in the English main proceeding) they would presumably have received<br />

under a local (secondary) proceeding - provided they would abstain from filing<br />

petitions for opening secondary proceedings. 29 The result of this promise and the<br />

creditors' trust in it was a considerable increase of the sales price.<br />

Finally, when the debtor's reorganization is at stake in the insolvency proceeding,<br />

the clarity of the two-person-relationship is of little or no help. The reason being<br />

that reorganization concentrates primarily on the rescue of the debtor; hence the<br />

advantage for the creditors is in fact just a kind of reflex of such rescue. 30 Only then,<br />

when the rescue is successful, will the creditors have the chance to recover what they<br />

have lost due to their debtor's insolvency. This mechanism is hard to describe or<br />

regulate in terms of a two-person-relationship-this model just does not work in<br />

such a context.<br />

In summary, the traditional maxim "one company, one insolvency, one<br />

proceeding" certainly does have its advantages and justifications. However, when<br />

the debtor's reorganization is at stake-be this the reorganization of the economic<br />

unit," or the reorganization of the legal entity itself 32 -holding on to this maxim<br />

threatens the result of achieving the highest value maximization.<br />

Thus the task is to find alternatives to the traditional rule which are better<br />

adapted to the modern insolvency law's prioritization of reorganization over<br />

liquidation. 33 For a German, the often celebrated and quite frequently copied<br />

approach of a unitary proceeding 3 " reveals a certain disadvantage. Without the<br />

initial division between these two types of proceedings, it is harder to ex ante predict<br />

the evolution of the case at hand and how it will be organized.<br />

Nevertheless, two options for a modernized treatment of group insolvencies are<br />

recognizable: the first is of a procedural aggregation, the second option is of a<br />

substantive aggregation. Option one proposes the procedural aggregation of the<br />

multiple proceedings. Numerous models exist so far. A rather prominent model is<br />

28. In the Matter of Collins & Aikman et. al, (2006) EWHC 1343 (Ch), available at http://www.eirdatabase.comldownload/cases/145/134-1_Collins-&-Aikman-IIl.pdf.<br />

29. See generally Natasha Watson, Comments on Collins & Aikman Europe SA and Other<br />

Companies, 11 INT'L CASE L. ALERT (2006) (providing an overview of the case), http://www.eirdatabase.com/download/caselaw/7/International-Caselaw---Alert-No-11-IV-2006-August-27,-2006.pdf.<br />

30. For an insightful discussion of this mechanism, see MANFRED BALZ, SANIERUNG VON<br />

UNTERNEHMEN ODER VON UNTERNEHMENSTRAGERN (1986).<br />

31. For example, the liquidation through the sale of the whole unit.<br />

32. Or, the debtor's reorganization in the strict sense.<br />

33. The following observation of Hertig and Kanda is noteworthy: "Creditors of the members of<br />

corporate groups are arguably more vulnerable to the opportunism and negligence of controlling<br />

shareholders than the creditors of... independent companies." HERTIG & KANDA, supra note 7, at 74 n.7.<br />

34. See Christoph G. Paulus, The New German Insolvency Code, 33 TEX. INT'L L.J. 141,143 (1998).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 826 2006-2007


2007 GROUP INSOLVENCIES - SOME THOUGHTS ABOUT NEW APPROACHES 827<br />

the appointment of just one insolvency administrator for all proceedings of the group<br />

members." The main advantage of that model is that frictional losses, through the<br />

cooperation of several administrators, are avoided. There is no need to exchange<br />

information to coordinate the proceedings or to cooperate in general. 36 Some<br />

experience with cases under the umbrella of the EIR leave the impression that the<br />

written version of these obligations is sweeter than their practical realization. The<br />

handling of the multiple proceedings is considerably more efficient. However, the<br />

main disadvantage of this approach is the administrator's potential loss of neutrality<br />

and independence; there is a certain realistic threat of a collision of interests. This<br />

might become visible when, for example, tort claims within the group structure are<br />

to be pursued or when one company possibly has a claw-back claim against the<br />

other. The appointment of a special examiner in such cases usually serves as a<br />

solution; but this does not always erase the appearance of conspiracy.<br />

A variant of this approach has been tested twice by the Insolvency Court of<br />

KIln (Cologne). After the opening of a main proceeding over the assets of the<br />

parent company in England, and the opening of a secondary proceeding over the<br />

assets of a subsidiary in Germany, the German judge declared that the English<br />

administrators were debtors in possession. This means under the relevant German<br />

rules 37 a custodian (Sachwalter) has to be appointed to monitor the debtor's actions<br />

and transactions. 38 In both proceedings, the judge in Cologne selected for this task<br />

an experienced German administrator, thereby leaving the English administrators<br />

sufficient freedom to act according to their overall plans and at the same time<br />

safeguarding the compliance with German law.<br />

Another way of combining the proceedings on a procedural level is to designate<br />

a single insolvency court as competent for the opening of the proceedings of all<br />

members of the group; usually this is the court in whose district the parent company<br />

is situated. Some modern laws, such as the Spanish one, do have such a rule; the<br />

EIR does not. As previously described, the attempt initiated by the English courts<br />

to interpret the EIR, nevertheless, as if it had this rule has received the<br />

aforementioned backlash through the ECJ's "Eurofood" decision.<br />

Finally, some commentators propose to cope with the problem of group<br />

insolvency law by means of cooperation duties among administrators. This implies,<br />

of course, that there are as many main proceedings as there are insolvent members<br />

of the group-thereby upholding the abovementioned traditional rule of "one<br />

company, one insolvency, one proceeding." This proposal has merit in that it avoids<br />

the somewhat tricky construction used quite often under the European Insolvency<br />

Regulation, which divides the insolvency proceedings of the group members into one<br />

main and several secondary proceedings despite the fact that each company is<br />

individually a legally separate entity. The proposal respects the separation of<br />

proceedings, and thus keeps the interference with existing concepts to a minimum.<br />

Pursuant to Art. 31 EIR, for instance, cooperation duties exist only between<br />

35. For an example from the U.S., see generally Blackwell v. Rio Mgt., Inc. (In re Blackwell),, 267<br />

B.R. 732 (Bankr. W.D. Tex. 2001).<br />

36. See generally art. 31 EIR, supra note 9, and 11 U.S.C. § 1525 ff.<br />

37. lnsolvenzordnung [Insolvency Act], Jan. 1, 1999 BGBI § 270 et seq. (F.R.G.).<br />

38. For a similar approach, see generally Maxwell Commc'n Corp. v. Societ6 Generale (In re Maxwell<br />

Commc'n Corp.), 170 B.R. 800 (Bankr. S.D. N.Y. 1994), affd 186 B.R. 807 (S.D. N.Y.), affd 93 F.3d 1036<br />

(2d Cir. 1996).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 827 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:819<br />

administrators in a main proceeding and the corresponding secondary proceedings.<br />

However, the concern remains that cooperation duties are more easily prescribed<br />

than fulfilled in practice.<br />

There might exist further possibilities to include even solvent group members<br />

into the procedural unity: One would be to establish a modification of the insolvency<br />

trigger "imminent insolvency". This would be a trigger which transforms the<br />

experience with the aforementioned domino effect into statutory language - for<br />

instance, "A member of an incorporated group shall be deemed to be faced with<br />

group-related insolvency if it is likely to be affected by the opened insolvency<br />

proceedings of other group members." 39 Another of the indicated possibilities is to<br />

have the phenomenon of group insolvency dealt with in a particular plan proceeding;<br />

thereby the solvent members of the group could be included into the group-wide<br />

plan without pulling them individually into an insolvency proceeding. A somewhat<br />

mitigated third possibility would be to establish for inter-group claims a particular<br />

avoidance rule or to declare group members throughout related entities - thereby<br />

alleviating the application of the existing avoidance rules." 0<br />

The second option-a substantive aggregation-is the thornier one. Under the<br />

term "substantive consolidation," substantive aggregation is admitted in the U.S. 4 '<br />

only when due to prior mismanagement the assets of the group members are so<br />

confused that the estates cannot be kept separate. One could call such a situation a<br />

kind of force majeure; factual obstacles impede compliance with the legal attribution<br />

of each individual right and duty to each individual legal entity.<br />

The question arises whether substantive consolidation should in fact be<br />

restrained to such force majeure or whether one should go a step further and extend<br />

this approach-of course, with all caution. 4 ' To be sure, asking this question does<br />

make sense only when and if there are advantages of consolidation over the mere<br />

procedural aggregation of the separate proceedings. The answer is positive because<br />

of increased efficiency which has supra been described as driving force behind the<br />

modernization of insolvency law. The increase of efficiency results not only from the<br />

appointment of just one administrator-this is achievable through a mere procedural<br />

aggregation as well, as shown supra-but also from the general applicability of just<br />

one law, the lex concursus.<br />

To be sure, even this is achievable through the designation of one competent<br />

court whose order commences the proceedings over each one of the group members.<br />

However, the threat remains that the single proceeding would be broken up into<br />

several secondary proceedings when local creditors file respective petitions. This<br />

threat could possibly be eliminated if the insolvency administrator of the one and<br />

only proceeding were given the exclusive right to file such petitions. However, so far<br />

such a rule does not exist. 4 3 A recent decision of the English Chancery Division in<br />

39. To be sure, this is meant to be just as a starting point for further necessary considerations.<br />

40. A somewhat harsher version of this proposal would be to declare inter-group claims as being<br />

generally subordinated to the claims of the general unsecured creditors.<br />

41. See generally David A. Skeel, Groups of Companies: Substantive Consolidation in the U.S., in THE<br />

CHALLENGES OF INSOLVENcY LAW REFORM IN THE 21' CENTURY 229 (Henry Peter et al. eds., 2006).<br />

42. See, e.g., Peter, supra note 8, at 205. For the argument against substantive consolidation for<br />

principal reasons, see Daniel Staehelin, No Substantive Consolidation in the Insolvency of Groups of<br />

Companies, in THE CHALLENGES OF INSOLVENCY LAW REFORM IN THE 21" CENTURY 213 (Henry Peter<br />

et al. eds., 2006).<br />

43. In the course of the discussion before the enactment of the EIR, the European Parliament wanted<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 828 2006-2007


2007<br />

GROUP INSOLVENCIES - SOME THOUGHTS ABOUT NEW APPROACHES<br />

the Collins & Aikman case" illustrates the advantage of a unitary proceeding. In<br />

order to prevent the opening of secondary proceedings, the English administrators<br />

of the main proceeding promised the local creditors the dividend that they were<br />

supposed to receive in case of their opened local insolvency proceeding despite the<br />

fact that the only applicable English insolvency provides for a different distribution<br />

scheme. What Justice Lindsay permitted would barely be acceptable under<br />

continental European law outside a plan proceeding; but the outcome of the case<br />

was a sale of the whole at a remarkably higher sales price. Thus, to apply just one<br />

law meant greater efficiency.<br />

The idea to explore extension of the substantive consolidation approach at all is<br />

the result of cases such as KPNQwest, which concerned a company that owned<br />

cables across Europe. Most of these cables formed networks; one of the bigger ones<br />

ran through Belgium, France, Germany, and the Netherlands. Notably, this<br />

particular network was-in terms of ownership-subdivided into four parts: the<br />

Belgian one was held by a Belgian subsidiary, the French one by a French subsidiary,<br />

and so on. Under such circumstances-would it not make sense to keep such an<br />

economic unit (this need not necessarily be the group as a whole) together with its<br />

respective insolvencies, at least when reorganization is at stake? The same principle<br />

could apply when a group (or parts of it) creates one product the components of<br />

which are built in subsidiaries.<br />

Posing these questions provokes deliberations about how much insolvency law<br />

is restricted to tools designed for use in times of economic success. Possible reasons<br />

for the creation of groups are: tax considerations; the need for rationalization or<br />

other organizational grounds; or a somewhat opaque complexity for various<br />

reasons. 4 ' These and other justifications can accumulate-as they often do when a<br />

group expands beyond the borders of a single jurisdiction. Eurofood is a typical<br />

example: the company was domiciled in Dublin for tax reasons, and its purpose was<br />

to serve the group as a whole. Therefore-once again the question: is it appropriate<br />

when the insolvency lawyer is bound to look only at each of the pieces of the jigsaw<br />

puzzle rather than seeing the picture as a whole?<br />

The answer is even less easy when this insolvency lawyer looks at his<br />

accumulated experiences: how often is the net number of group members used for<br />

purposes of shifting gains or losses from here to there-subsidiary x has to buy goods<br />

for a rather high price in order to sell it at a rather low price to subsidiary y which<br />

shall thereby (through an improved statement of financial conditions) be prepared<br />

for sale at a rather high price. German administrators term this strategy "to<br />

decorate the bride," for increasing the bride price. This is but one example of how -<br />

seen from an ex post perspective of an insolvency lawyer-the separation of legal<br />

independent entities is fairly often (ab)used for purposes that make sense only when<br />

the group is seen and understood as a whole.<br />

In sight of that, it is somewhat artificial to imply that creditors are creditors of<br />

just a particular debtor. If obligations and rights are shifted back and forth within<br />

to have Article 29 restricted in this way. See Christoph G. Paulus, A Theoretical Approach to Cooperation<br />

in Transnational Insolvencies: A European Perspective, 11 EUR. BUSINESS L.R., 435 (2000).<br />

44. See Re Collins & Aikman Europe SA, [2006] EWHC 1343 (Ch.) (U.K.).<br />

45. See Neil Cooper, GRIP 21, Corporate Groups & Insolvency (Jan. 12, 2005).<br />

http://www.grip2l.org/uk/actualites/actualites.php?idactualite=41.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 829 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:819<br />

the group during its time of successful economic performance, it is more often than<br />

not accidental whether the particular debtor is still the real debtor and whether it is<br />

solvent. In general, the concentration on the debtor-creditor relationship (stemming<br />

from one of the most fantastic inventions of ancient Roman law) has become<br />

outdated in modern time when looked at from the global trade of both performing<br />

as well as non-performing loans. These observations, however, lead right into a wide<br />

field of further very fundamental questions about the law's role in general. This is<br />

not the place to present additional outlooks. Such discussions must be left for<br />

separate treatises on philosophy of law as well as methodology of law.<br />

Therefore, suffice it to conclude that it is possible to extend the concept of<br />

substantive consolidation in reorganization proceedings beyond the confusion of<br />

assets and estates. This, however, is certainly not yet the end of the necessary<br />

deliberations; after all, to pack all assets into one estate does not necessarily<br />

correspond with the economic realities. There is some fine-tuning necessary that<br />

shall not be developed here to its full extent; this requires additional thought and<br />

discussion. As an indication of how such fine-tuning could look, consider an<br />

obligatory formation of creditors' groups in a plan of a group insolvency.<br />

Accordingly, all creditors of each member company necessarily form one group.<br />

Another tool would be to provide inter-group claims with a certain ranking system<br />

such as the one that exists under German law, where claims of shareholders based on<br />

equity replacing loans to the company are subordinated.<br />

These are just two examples of many other possibilities. I hope that I have<br />

shown that it appears to be worthwhile to keep thinking along these lines and to add<br />

to increasing insolvency law's overall efficiency.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 830 2006-2007


Legal Mercantile Evolution from the<br />

Twentieth Century to the Dawning of the<br />

Twenty-First Century<br />

ARCELIA QUINTANA-ADRIANO*<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. INTRO D U CTIO N ................................................................................................... 831<br />

II. GENERAL AGREEMENT ON TARIFFS AND TRADE .......................................... 834<br />

III. W ORLD TRADE O RGANIZATION ...................................................................... 836<br />

IV . BY W AY OF SYNTH ESIS ...................................................................................... 840<br />

V . C O N C LU SIO N ....................................................................................................... 84 1<br />

I. INTRODUCTION<br />

The need to establish commercial regulations in the foreign arena became<br />

manifest at the turn of the twentieth century and the beginning of the twenty-first<br />

century, mainly as a result of the problems brought about by internal regulations of<br />

nation states devoted to international trade. The nation states played an active and<br />

marked role in establishing their own commercial regulations in order to maintain a<br />

good balance in this area and to boost an incipient domestic industry. Nonetheless,<br />

all of these national laws proved that there was no adequate regulation for<br />

commercial transactions at a world-wide level. The lack of such international<br />

regulations was a reflection of the commercial policies in use by the nation states<br />

which, far from boosting commercial activities, restricted global commercial turnover<br />

and prevented foreign economies from profiting from comparative costs. In other<br />

words, they denied the possibility to acquire imported goods in areas where such<br />

goods were produced at lower costs.<br />

' Doctor of <strong>Law</strong>, Universidad Nacional Aut6noma de M6xico (UNAM). Permanent professor of<br />

Commercial <strong>Law</strong>, Economic <strong>Law</strong>, and History of Economic Thinking for degree level; Commercial <strong>Law</strong><br />

and Financial <strong>Law</strong> at the Postgraduate Studies Section of the Faculty of <strong>Law</strong> and the Faculty of<br />

Accountancy and Management, UNAM. Professor at the UNAM. Permanent researcher by examination<br />

in Commercial <strong>Law</strong> at the Institute of <strong>Law</strong> Research, UNAM. Member of the National System of<br />

Researchers (SNI) of the National Council for Science and Technology (CONACYT), Mexico.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 831 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:831<br />

Consequently, the methods or policies employed by national governmentssuch<br />

as restrictions of certain fields in domestic industries, the benefit of exportsthe<br />

commercial privileges for dominant countries over colonies, the increase of<br />

customs barriers, and the direct control of imports and financial regulation-not only<br />

damaged and impoverished developing countries, but also became the main reason<br />

for initiating international trade regulations, with the fundamental purpose of<br />

developing alternative courses against governmental-driven measures.<br />

The first attempts to establish the aforementioned commercial regulations were<br />

consolidated through the signing of bilateral and regional treaties, with the aim of<br />

reducing tariffs and other restrictions. However, in order for these agreements to<br />

come into effect and to avoid any kind of possible international discrimination-as<br />

they only included commercial benefits for the few signing countries-it was<br />

necessary for these treaties to be signed on multilateral grounds.<br />

It was only after World War I, when the League of Nations was established in<br />

1919, that a movement for the systematic regulation of international trade on a<br />

multilateral basis began. Although the League of Nations had limited duties in the<br />

economic field, it had no responsible body for commerce. Mercantile affairs were<br />

still conducted with traditional methods, that is, bilateral negotiations and<br />

international diplomatic conferences. The failure of the League of Nations-due to<br />

the United <strong>State</strong>s' refusal to become a member, even though its president had been<br />

the driving force behind the foundation of this society-had a deep impact on the<br />

negotiations of all international treaties that did not receive support from the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s, at the time one of the leading world powers.<br />

This was the reason why the world economy experienced a profound, dramatic,<br />

and memorable crisis in the 1920s, which gave rise to, among other things, the<br />

outbreak of World War .II, a conflict that might have been prevented had the<br />

economy succeeded in becoming both a thriving commercial growth and an<br />

expansionist world system. From 1920 to 1930, however, the most significant<br />

attempts to reinstate world economy were the Brussels Financial Conference, held in<br />

1920 to establish the financial and economic principles for the governments to<br />

follow, and the Conference for the Abolition of Prohibitions and Restrictions on<br />

Imports and Exports, held in 1927, where some decisions were made concerning a<br />

reduction of tariffs and other trade barriers, along with the approval of an<br />

Agreement for the abolition of prohibitions and restrictions on imports and exports.<br />

However, the Conference failed, and the Agreement never really came into effect.<br />

The Great Depression-a result of, among other things, low foreign trade<br />

growth, in contrast with high production taxes-led to an industrial contraction, a<br />

deep financial crisis, and an increase in protectionist measures assumed by the nation<br />

states. Protectionism was varied and widespread. The main industrialized countries<br />

increased tariffs and introduced quantitative restrictions and change controls, while<br />

bilateral agreements on clearing exchange multiplied, seemingly decreasing the<br />

possibility of establishing multilateral foundations to regulate foreign trade. Given<br />

the 1929 depression and financial crisis, governments adopted measures to safeguard<br />

their economies and products, neglecting the potential effects of such policies on<br />

other nations and creating new commercial restrictions, such as a direct quantitative<br />

control on imports, economic restrictions, preferential areas, bilateral commercial<br />

agreements, higher tariff barriers, strengthening of commercial areas with<br />

discriminatory protection, and establishment of direct subsidies to a number of<br />

industries destined to help national economies. This protectionism prevailed<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 832 2006-2007


2007<br />

LEGAL MERCANTILE EVOLUTION<br />

throughout the 1930s. In 1941, both the Unites <strong>State</strong>s and the United Kingdom<br />

attempted to establish a series of basic principles to regulate world trade exchange<br />

after the war, but to no avail.<br />

After World War II, nation states became aware of the impending need to<br />

prevent commercial restrictions. An international consensus was reached, declaring<br />

that to restore non-discriminatory commercial conditions, commerce should be<br />

liberalized and freed from the protectionist measures that had been in effect since<br />

the 1930s. The Nation Sates were also concerned with the devastating effects of<br />

World War 1I. In order to avoid another conflict of this magnitude, they decided to<br />

create a substitute for the "Society of Nations," called the United Nations, whose<br />

tasks included international cooperation toward the solution of international<br />

financial problems. 1<br />

Having the reorganization of world economy as its main objective, the United<br />

Nations' Monetary and Financial Conference, known as the Bretton Woods<br />

Conference, was held in 1944.2 Through the creation of three international bodies, a<br />

strategy was established to reorganize the world economy and foreign trade. These<br />

bodies were the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the International Bank for<br />

Reconstruction and Promotion-better known as the World Bank (WB)-and the<br />

International Trade Organization (ITO). Each of the bodies in this tripartite<br />

international economic system had a specific goal. The original idea contemplated<br />

specific tasks for each of these bodies:<br />

The IMF would only deal with macroeconomic issues of the concerned<br />

country-that is, its budget deficit, its monetary policy, its inflation, its commercial<br />

deficit, and its foreign debt-thereby guaranteeing order and stability in<br />

international financial transactions.<br />

The WB would seek to promote investment and would also deal with structural<br />

issues. It would not regulate the public expenditure, financial institutions, labour<br />

market, and commercial policies of each nation state.<br />

The ITO was to lay out commercial rules to facilitate the liberalization of<br />

multilateral trade, including employment regulations, agreements on basic products,<br />

restrictive trade practices, foreign investment, and services.<br />

On December 27, 1945, the Articles of Agreement of the IMF were signed.'<br />

However, it was not until October 15 of that year that it became a specialized body<br />

of the United Nations. Its aims were to contribute to the creation of an adequate<br />

and more stable international monetary system by decreasing payment balance<br />

problems in participating countries.<br />

The WB came into operation at the beginning of 1947. In its origins, the Bank<br />

had the purpose of funding the need for reconstruction of European countries after<br />

1. The term "United Nations" was first used on January 1, 1942, during World War II, when<br />

representatives of twenty-six nations approved the Declaration of United Nations by virtue of which their<br />

respective governments committed to struggle in tandem against the Axis Powers (Germany, Japan, and<br />

Italy). However, it was only until 1945 that the representatives of fifty countries gathered in San Francisco,<br />

California, at the United Nations Conference for International Organization to write the UN Charter. The<br />

United Nations Organization officially began its duties on October 24, 1945. See generally U.N. CHARTER.<br />

2. See United Nations Monetary Fund Financial Conference (Bretton Woods, N.H., July 1-22, 1944)<br />

Proceedings and Documents 94, U.S. Dept. of <strong>State</strong> Pub. No. 2866.<br />

3. See International Monetary Fund (IMF) Web site, http://www.imf.org.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 833 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:831<br />

Wold War II, granting equal consideration and facilities for projects and resources<br />

devoted to development and reconstruction.<br />

The negotiations for the creation of the ITO began at the United Nations<br />

Conference on Trade and Employment, held in 1947 in Havana, Cuba (Havana<br />

Conference).' The Havana Charter, a product of this Conference, listed four main<br />

aspects for trade liberalization: (1) economic development and reconstruction; (2)<br />

equal conditions for market accessing, supply resources, and production means; (3)<br />

elimination of commercial barriers; and (4) cooperation within the International<br />

Trade Organization.' The Havana Charter additionally established the General<br />

Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT]), to be regulated by the ITO. This<br />

document had been under negotiation since December 1945 to decrease and<br />

consolidate customs duties. The IMF was also to regulate this document, defining<br />

respective jurisdictions and, above all, safeguarding the IMF's authority over<br />

macroeconomic and monetary issues. It also considered a division of responsibilities.<br />

The Final Act of the Havana Conference was signed by fifty-three countries, with an<br />

appendix of the resolutions taken by the Internal Commission of the International<br />

Trade Organization. 6 The validity of this Final Act was conditioned to an<br />

international ratification by the countries comprising at least eighty-five percent of<br />

all world trade.'<br />

Ratification by the United <strong>State</strong>s was decisive. Yet Congress, which appeared<br />

to be the party most interested in establishing the ITO, refused to sign the Charter<br />

because it was not liberal enough. 8 As a result, some governments, unwilling to<br />

submit their regulations to an organization which could have power over their trade<br />

regulations, did not ratify the Act either. The Charter to establish the ITO was not<br />

ratified by the requisite number of countries, and all attempts to establish a<br />

multilateral trading organization were abandoned.<br />

II.<br />

GENERAL AGREEMENT ON TARIFFS AND TRADE<br />

Concerned with safeguarding the tariff concessions negotiated during the<br />

Havana Conference, twenty-three governments called for their provisional approval<br />

while the ITO was being consolidated. As a result, in October 1947, Australia,<br />

Belgium, Brazil, Burma, Canada, Cuba, Czechoslovakia, Chile, China, France, India,<br />

Lebanon, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Pakistan, South<br />

Africa, South Rhodesia, Syria, Sri Lanka, the United Kingdom, and the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s approved the GATT, which had been under negotiation since the end of 1945<br />

and during the Havana meetings. 9 The GATT" established regulations on mutual<br />

tariffs, traffic trade, tariff valuation, free trade areas, subsidies, fees, and non-tariff<br />

barriers. It went into effect on January 1, 1948.1°<br />

4. See United Nations, Conference on Trade and Employment, Havana, Cuba, Nov. 21-24, 1948, Final<br />

Act and Related Documents, UN Doc. E/Conf.2178 (1948), 21.7.3(b).<br />

5. See United Nations Conference on Trade and Employment, March 1948, Havana Charter for an<br />

International Trade Organization, art. 11(2), U.N. Sales No. 48.II.D.4, E/CONF.2/78 (1948).<br />

6. See id.<br />

7. See id.<br />

8. See id.<br />

9. General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), Oct. 30, 1947, art. III, para 8(b), 61 Stat. A-11,<br />

55 U.N.T.S. 194, available at http://www.gatt.org.<br />

10. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 834 2006-2007


2007<br />

LEGAL MERCANTILE EVOLUTION<br />

Without the ratification of the Havana Charter, the ITO never came into being.<br />

Consequently the GATT became a provisional mechanism to govern foreign trade<br />

and the only multilateral framework that established foreign exchange regulations.<br />

GATT negotiations were of little value for poor countries because very few efforts<br />

were aimed at eliminating trade restrictions of elaborate products or at protecting<br />

agriculture. Such difficulties drove developing countries to ask the UN to create an<br />

organization in charge of examining world trade issues.<br />

Taking the position of developing countries into account, the UN Economic<br />

and Social Council (ECOSOC) decided in 1942 to convene a Conference on Trade<br />

and Development, which was hosted in Geneva, Switzerland in 1964. All members<br />

of the United Nations attended. The Conference established the United Nations<br />

Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD)" to deal with foreign trade<br />

problems. Hence, two independent organizations for international trade arose, but<br />

with no clear distinction between them: the GATT and the UNCTAD.<br />

The GAIT ultimately turned out to be a formal provisional agreement that<br />

made the 1947-approved tariff concessions possible, as it required no ratification. 2<br />

However, the adoption of some regulations related to certain points did not match<br />

the domestic legislation of several contrasting parties, so they reached an agreement<br />

on a "Protocol of Provisional Application," known as the Grandfather Clause. 3 This<br />

clause stipulated that each <strong>State</strong> was to put GATT principles into practice insofar as<br />

they were compatible with their current legislation.'"<br />

Despite having been conceived as a provisional commercial agreement, the<br />

GATT helped establish a stable and thriving multilateral trade system.<br />

Nevertheless, and possibly due to its provisional nature, some regional integration<br />

processes continued; for example, with a view to liberalizing trade, Latin American<br />

countries established the Latin American Free Trade Association (LAFTA) in<br />

1960."5 Twenty years later, LAFTA would become the Latin American Integration<br />

Association (LAIA). 6<br />

Eight rounds of negotiations were held during the GATT's nearly fifty years of<br />

existence. The rounds were aimed at specific subjects of foreign trade, such as tariff<br />

duties, commercial policies, trade barriers, subsidies, antidumping, safeguards, and<br />

technical assistance to developing countries, among others. Negotiations throughout<br />

the first four rounds were bilateral. From the Dollon, Switzerland Round in 1960<br />

onward, the European Economic Community acted on behalf of all its<br />

representatives, and thus the negotiations took on a multilateral nature.<br />

Nevertheless the GATT evidently was in need of reorganization, which led to the<br />

Uruguay Round in the 1980s and, finally, to the establishment of the World Trade<br />

Organization (WTO).<br />

11. During the Geneva Conference, it was resolved that UNCTAD would meet on a four-year basis,<br />

with a possibility to hold intergovernmental meetings among conferences. Also, it was decided that a<br />

permanent Secretariat would provide any needed support.<br />

12. See generally GATT, supra note 9.<br />

13. Protocol of Provisional Application, T.I.A.S. 1700, 55 U.N.T.S. 308.<br />

14. Id.<br />

15. Treaty of Montevideo, Feb. 18. 1960, 2 B.D.I.E.L. 54.<br />

16. See Treaty of Montevideo, Aug. 12, 1980,1329 U.N.T.S. 255, 20 I.L.M. 672 (1981).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 835 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:831<br />

III. WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION<br />

The GATT Ministerial <strong>Meeting</strong> held in 1982 in Geneva laid the foundations for<br />

the negotiation program set out at the Punta del Este, Uruguay Round, in<br />

September 1986. The goals of this Round were focused on the liberalization and<br />

expansion of world trade, updating and strengthening GATT regulations by<br />

improving the multilateral system, promoting international cooperation to<br />

strengthen the interplay of commercial policies and those affecting the growth of<br />

world trade, and expanding its application to new areas in international commerce,<br />

such as services, agriculture, textiles, and intellectual property. 17 The Ministerial<br />

<strong>State</strong>ment, a product of the 1982 meeting, turned out to be the mandate governing<br />

the negotiations of Uruguay's 1986 Round. This <strong>State</strong>ment focused on two main<br />

aspects-the first being negotiations about trade in goods, whereas the second<br />

referred to the characteristics and goals of negotiations regarding foreign trade in<br />

services.<br />

Coincidentally, in the 1980s, the changes in world trade since the GATT was<br />

signed in 1947 became self-evident. Economic globalization was developing, as was<br />

trade in services, for which the GATT had not established any regulations.<br />

Moreover, there had been an increase in the number of and interest in foreign<br />

investments.<br />

The Uruguay Round-which lasted from 1986 to 1994, with the participation of<br />

108 countries-represented an opportunity for liberalizing trade, reinforcing<br />

discipline, and improving the openness of the multilateral trade system. In addition,<br />

it sought to constitute a mechanism to settle commercial controversies. With a view<br />

to fulfilling the goals established in the Ministerial <strong>State</strong>ment, thirteen negotiation<br />

groups were created, together with a special group for trade in services-related<br />

negotiations, which included customs duties, non-tariff measures, tropical products,<br />

products obtained from the exploitation of natural resources, textiles and clothing,<br />

agriculture, articles from the Agreement, safeguards, agreements on multilateral<br />

trade negotiations, 8 subsidies and compensatory measures, trade-related aspects of<br />

intellectual property rights, antidumping, and measures for trade-related<br />

investments.<br />

Finally, after almost forty-seven years of planning a multilateral organization to<br />

regulate world trade, the agreements of the Uruguay Round were finally signed in<br />

Marrakech, Morocco in April 1994.'9 The international community was at long last<br />

able to consolidate the creation and operation of the World Trade Organization<br />

(WTO)!<br />

17. See generally Final Act Embodying the Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade<br />

Negotiations, Apr. 15, 1994, LEGAL INSTRUMENTS -RESULTS OFTHE URUGUAY ROUND, vol. 1 (1994)1 33<br />

I.L.M. 1125 (1994) [hereinafter Uruguay Round Final Act].<br />

18. As for the WTO, the term multilateral describes all activities on a world basis, specifically between<br />

all members of the WTO; they are to be distinguished from regional activities or those carried out by<br />

smaller countries.<br />

19. See Uruguay Round Final Act, supra note 17.<br />

20. See generally Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, Apr. 15, 1994<br />

LEGAL INSTRUMENTS-RESULTS OF THE URUGUAY ROUND vol. 31,33 I.L.M. 1144 (1994), 1867 U.N.T.S.<br />

154, Pub. L. 103-465, 108 Stat. 4809 (1994), 19 U.S.C 3501. The approval decree of the Final Act from<br />

GAT]r Uruguay Round was published in Mexico on August 4, 1994, in the Diario Oficial de la Federaci6n.<br />

On December 30 of the same year, all agreements were put into effect and therefore the validity of the<br />

World Trade Organization in Mexican law became applicable as well.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 836 2006-2007


2007<br />

LEGAL MERCANTILE EVOLUTION<br />

The signing of the Final Act by representatives of the 128 member countries,<br />

the result of long years of negotiations, culminated with the creation of the World<br />

Trade Organization. 2 Several agreements, understandings, and statements were<br />

thus formalized that undoubtedly constitute the regulating legal instrument of trade<br />

at a multilateral level. The WTO became the most significant modification to the<br />

1947 GATT and, in turn, managed to consolidate itself as an actual multilateral trade<br />

organization, a goal that the GATT was never able to accomplish.<br />

The Agreement through which the World Trade Organization was established<br />

holds the following tenets, already considered by the GATT' in 1947, and which are<br />

to be abided by the world trade domain: 1) a discrimination-free trading system; 2)<br />

promotion of loyal competition; 3) fewer trade barriers; and 4) promotion of<br />

development and economic reform. 3<br />

As a seminal part of its commercial policy, the WTO also keeps a nondiscriminatory<br />

treatment principle, according to which all members of the<br />

organization are equals and abide by the same trade parameters, regardless of their<br />

economic or governmental system. This tenet is expounded through two basic<br />

clauses. The Most-Favoured Nation Clause states that any privilege or advantage<br />

granted by a WTO member to a country shall be extended or accorded to other<br />

members. 24 The National Treatment Clause states that all imported products from<br />

any contracting party into another one's territory shall not be directly or indirectly<br />

be subject to taxation or internal charges higher to those applied for similar domestic<br />

products. 29<br />

The multilateral legal regime created through the establishment of the World<br />

Trade Organization has broadened, as more clauses and goals in new trade areas<br />

have been included, such as services and intellectual property. Rights and<br />

obligations assumed by contracting parties under the earlier GATT scheme were<br />

also significantly modified by the WTO.<br />

The WTO was created to guarantee the development of trade relations<br />

between members and to negotiate and monitor the performance of the new<br />

obligations they have assumed. Consideration is given to the multilateral trade<br />

institutional legal basis and the common framework for the development of such<br />

relations, as well as to its role as a forum for multilateral negotiations, designed to<br />

raise standards of living and to increase production and trade in services and goods.<br />

The main purpose of the World Trade Organization is to develop a more<br />

feasible multilateral trade system than the one established by the GATT in 1947.<br />

The WTO has established as one of its essential goals that developing and leastdeveloped<br />

countries may benefit from the growth of international trade. 6<br />

The means by which the WTO plans to fulfil its purposes are established in the<br />

signing of agreements directed to obtain-on a reciprocity basis-a significant<br />

21. See Uruguay Round Final Act, supra note 17.<br />

22. Vincent Ferraro, Anna Cristine Santos, & Julie Ginocchio, The Global Trading System, available<br />

at http://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/intrel/bush/tradepaper.htm.<br />

23. See PETER VAN DEN BOSSCHE. THE LAW AND POLICY OF THE WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION<br />

39-44 (2005).<br />

24. GATT supra note 9, art. 1, para. 1.<br />

25. GAT supra note 9, art. III, para. 2.<br />

26. Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, pmbl., para. 2, available at<br />

http:/www.wto.org/English/docs-e/legal-e/04-wto.pdf<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 837 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:831<br />

decrease in tariffs and other trade barriers. This includes developing a lasting,<br />

integrated multilateral trade system, comprising the 1947 GAT, the results of<br />

previous efforts for trade liberalization, as well as the results from the Uruguay<br />

Round.<br />

As established, the Uruguay Round's Final Act puts an end to the provisional<br />

nature of the 1947 GATT through the creation of the World Trade Organization,<br />

with the purpose of facilitating cooperation among its members for the development<br />

of business relations and with legal status, organs of its own, and ample functions. 7<br />

The organic structure of the WTO is constituted by a Ministerial Conference acting<br />

as its main organ, overseeing the Dispute Settlement Body, the General Council, and<br />

the Trade Policy Review Body.<br />

The relevance of this Act stems from the fact that it integrates three major<br />

agreements under the same structure: (1) GATT, the merchandise agreement 28 ; (2)<br />

the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) 29 ; and (3) the Agreement on<br />

Trade-related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS). 3 " These agreements<br />

are managed by three Councils-Trade in Goods, Trade in Services, and Trade-<br />

Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, which in turn are managed by the<br />

General Council, with the main task of supervising the performance and application<br />

of their respective multilateral agreements.<br />

At the same time, two international mechanisms were considered-an<br />

understanding concerning the regulations and procedures to settle differences, as<br />

well as a mechanism to analyze business policies. In addition, cooperation between<br />

the WTO and other specialized foreign organizations, mainly the IMF and the WB,<br />

were foreseen.<br />

The incorporation of regulations for trade in services under the legal apparatus<br />

of the WTO undoubtedly made a difference between the GATT's proposed system<br />

and its own. The GATS is the first and only set of multilateral regulations governing<br />

foreign trade in services. It came into being in response to the huge growth of the<br />

economy of services during the thirty years prior to the formalization of the WTO<br />

and the trade increase in this field, largely brought about by the revolution in<br />

communications.<br />

The GATS is the framework for the performance of both governments and<br />

individuals, and it is divided into two parts: the main agreement containing<br />

regulations and general controls, and national lists including concrete commitments<br />

by each country regarding access to foreign suppliers in domestic markets. 31 Still,<br />

regardless of commitments with certain service sectors, the GATS allows<br />

governments to control foreign suppliers' activities in the domestic market. This<br />

control takes the form of restricting market access and domestic regulatory changes<br />

established in the list of a country's commitments.<br />

27. See generally, Uruguay Round Final Act, supra note 17.<br />

28. GATT, supra note 9, art. VII.<br />

29. General Agreement on Trade in Services, Apr. 15, 1994, Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the<br />

World Trade Organization, supra note 26, Annex lB.<br />

30. Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, Apr. 15, 1994, Marrakesh<br />

Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, supra note 26, Annex IC [hereinafter TRIPS],<br />

available at http://www.wto.orglenglish/docs-e/legal-e/27-trips_01_e.htm.<br />

31. See GATS, supra note 29, Parts II-III.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 838 2006-2007


2007<br />

LEGAL MERCANTILE EVOLUTION<br />

The GATS comprises all services subject to foreign trade, except for those<br />

supplied to the public according to governmental power and, in the field of air<br />

transport, traffic rights and all services directly related to the exercising of traffic<br />

rights. In this context, encouraged by the rapid and significant business opening of<br />

different foreign markets, a regulation of financial services was decided to be<br />

included into the World Trade Organization during the Uruguay Round<br />

negotiations, specifically under the GATS. These services involved banks,<br />

insurance, values, factoring, leasing, finance, or any other related or auxiliary service.<br />

Regulation of trade in services by the WTO has proved to be a deciding factor<br />

and is currently considered one of the main features of every trade agreement.<br />

Hence, the WTO, acting as the main multilateral trade-oriented organization, has<br />

established the principles the financial services sector must follow through the<br />

GATS, within a framework directed to governments and individuals.<br />

The GATS allows countries to concede additional credibility to their financialsystem<br />

liberalization programs. GATS specifically facilitates the organization of<br />

reforms made in the international arena.<br />

Regulations governing foreign trade in services, established in the GATS,<br />

include three main elements: 1) an agreed framework stipulating basic obligations<br />

applicable to all member countries; 2) national lists of commitments where other<br />

specific domestic commitments are considered and subject to a constant<br />

liberalization process; and 3) appendices concerning the particular state of affairs of<br />

different service sectors. 32<br />

The appendix on financial services, chiefly banks and insurance services,<br />

establishes the rights of parties, notwithstanding what has been stated elsewhere, to<br />

adopt cautionary measures-such as security measures for investors, depositors, and<br />

policy-holders-and to guarantee the integrity and stability of the financial system.<br />

There is, however, still another financial service-related understanding that allows<br />

interested competitors to make commitments related to financial services by means<br />

of a different process.<br />

Regarding access to markets, this understanding involves more detailed<br />

obligations, such as the following: 1) monopoly rights and cross-border trade; 2)<br />

signing of particular insurance and reinsurance policies; 3) processing and transfer of<br />

financial data; 4) rights to establish or expand trade presence; and 5) temporary<br />

entry of people." 3<br />

Domestic treatment-related dispositions expressly concern both access to<br />

payment systems and compensation managed by public bodies, as well as official<br />

means for funding and refunding. At the same time, consideration is given to<br />

affiliation or access to self-regulating institutions, futures and stock markets, and<br />

compensation organizations, or their mutual participation.<br />

Since trade in services is closely linked to circulating capital, the boundary<br />

between particular instruments of monetary policy and the necessary regulation is<br />

too narrow, resulting in the importance of clarifying these issues. Due to the<br />

susceptibility of the economical apparatus to financial imbalances, more caution for<br />

its liberalization must be taken than in other sectors. Therefore, when negotiating<br />

32. See id.<br />

33. See Understanding on Commitments in Financial Services 325, 33 I.L.M. 1168 (1994)<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 839 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:831<br />

these services, both domestic policies and the degree of development of different<br />

members are to be considered.<br />

The GATS includes a stipulated exception, the "chain-exclusion effect," that is<br />

likely to (1) lead to differing interpretations, whether a dispute-settling procedure is<br />

used or whether new negotiations are undertaken to define and specify the features<br />

of services provided by means of governmental power, and to (2) determine services<br />

not provided under commercial conditions. This exception is only defined regarding<br />

the financial services sector. Thus, "services provided by means of governmental<br />

power" are defined in Section b, Article 1 of the financial services appendix as (1)<br />

activities performed by a central bank or monetary authority or any other public<br />

body in pursuit of monetary or foreign exchange policies, (2) as part of a legal<br />

system of social security or public retirement plans, and (3) any related activity<br />

carried out by public bodies either on its own or under <strong>State</strong> guarantee or with<br />

financial resources provided by the <strong>State</strong>. As to "services," this term will imply the<br />

aforementioned activities when a member allows its financial service suppliers to<br />

carry out these activities in competition with a public entity or with another financial<br />

service supplier.<br />

Thus, instead of defining services and adding a list of services covered by the<br />

GATS, the decision was made to include all services, except for those supplied by<br />

means of governmental power, and to formulate a four-fold classification for trade in<br />

services, allowing members to take on specific commitments concerning the different<br />

ways to conduct such services in the different included sectors.<br />

IV. By WAY OF SYNTHESIS<br />

Trade between different nations has played a fundamental economic and<br />

cultural role. It has given rise to institutions, such as the bill of exchange, which in<br />

foreign trade bears extraordinary significance.' Yet, because of its own nature, it<br />

has been forced to face the problem of diverse legal regimes from different countries<br />

under which mercantile traffic has taken place. It is in connection with this that a<br />

consistent and integrated movement emerged based on mercantile law.<br />

The frequency of transactions among nation states gave rise to a need to<br />

orchestrate some regulations regarding world trade, as is the case with contracts.<br />

Consequently, throughout the twentieth century and until the dawning of the<br />

twenty-first, such <strong>State</strong>s have focused on seeking an integrated world trade<br />

regulation. 35<br />

Ever since the Middle Ages, and remarkably since the end of the nineteenth<br />

century and the beginning of the twentieth century, nation states devoted to<br />

commerce have intervened to maintain favourable trade balances abroad and to<br />

promote the development of a budding domestic industry. The policies in use<br />

damaged and impoverished developing countries, and the establishment of trade<br />

regulations at a multilateral scale was deemed essential. This regulation first<br />

materialized after World War II with the creation of the League of Nations, which<br />

was restructured after the war and gave way to the United Nations. The economic<br />

34. Explanatory Note by the UNCITRAL Secretariat on the United Nations Convention on<br />

International Bills of Exchange and International Promissory Notes, para. 5. Dec. 9, 1988.<br />

http://www.jus.uio.no/Im/un.bills.of.exchange.and.promissory.notes.convention.1988/doc.html#634.<br />

35. See VAN DEN BOSSCHE, supra note 23, at 35-38, 78-85.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 840 2006-2007


2007<br />

LEGAL MERCANTILE EVOLUTION<br />

protectionism between both world wars, however, led to an increase in tariffs and a<br />

multiplication of bilateral agreements of compensated exchange."<br />

By the end of World War II, and with a view to avoid a similar crisis to that of<br />

1929, a United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference was held, with the aim<br />

to create a tripartite international economic system, encompassing the IMF, the WB,<br />

and the ITO.<br />

The International Monetary Fund and the International Bank for<br />

Reconstruction and Development began working in 1945 and 1947, respectively.<br />

The ITO, on the other hand, was never able to materialize, due to a denial by the<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s to ratify the Agreement. In its place, to safeguard previously<br />

negotiated tariff concessions, a General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GAF)<br />

was ratified in 1947 with provisional status.<br />

The GATT enabled the implementation of tariff duties agreed therein. In<br />

addition, it also contributed to establish a thriving, sound multilateral trade system.<br />

However, expansion of world trade and enormous technological breakthroughs has<br />

made it increasingly necessary to update and strengthen GATT regulations.<br />

The 1982 GATT Ministerial <strong>Meeting</strong> held in Geneva agreed to host a Round in<br />

Punta del Este, Uruguay-the eighth to be held at the time. The Uruguay Round<br />

began in 1986 and negotiations came to an end in 1994 with the signing of the Final<br />

Act, which finally led to the creation a multilateral organization to regulate<br />

international trade-the World Trade Organization.<br />

V. CONCLUSION<br />

As noted, the development of a multilateral trade organization was a process<br />

that lasted over fifty years, beginning with the creation of the League of Nations in<br />

1919 until the establishment of the World Trade Organization in 1994. Its relevance<br />

within foreign trade stems not only from its having been constituted as the<br />

multilateral institutional legal basis and shared framework for the development of<br />

commercial relations among its members, but also from having integrated three<br />

agreements into a single structure of great relevance for foreign trade: the<br />

Merchandise Agreement (GAT), the Services Agreement (GATS), and Trade-<br />

Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS).<br />

During the twentieth century, trade developed to the extent that it became an<br />

international phenomenon. As such, <strong>State</strong>s have needed to take this into<br />

consideration by not only opening their borders to foreign merchandise, but also<br />

signing international agreements and taking part in multinational bodies and<br />

organizations that have been increasingly consolidated within the regulation arena of<br />

foreign trade.<br />

Markets have been driven by globalization and internationalization these last<br />

years, which is nothing but a search for mutually beneficial and productive<br />

specializations. Nevertheless, opening up to free trade requires a solid foundation to<br />

guarantee loyal competition within the arena of foreign trade. Nation states have<br />

attempted to work in consonance with the world order of commercial laws, evolving<br />

36. See generally Douglas A. Irwin, Historical Perspectives on U.S. Trade Policy,<br />

http://www.nber.org/reporter/winter99/irwin.html.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 841 2006-2007


842 TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL VOL. 42:831<br />

to the rhythm of legal international trade harmonization. Hopefully, future regional<br />

and multilateral negotiations generations will be able to keep on developing for the<br />

benefit of emerging economies.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 842 2006-2007


The Agricultural Exemption in Antitrust <strong>Law</strong>:<br />

A Comparative Look at the Political Economy<br />

of Market Regulation<br />

ARIE REICH*<br />

In Memory of Shlomo Lubin<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. INTR O D U CTIO N ................................................................................................... 844<br />

II. THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN U.S. LAW .............................................. 846<br />

III. THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN EC LAW ............................................... 849<br />

IV. THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN THE UNITED KINGDOM ...................... 854<br />

V. THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ISRAELI LAW ....................................... 857<br />

A. Background: Israel's Competition <strong>Law</strong> .................................................... 857<br />

B. The Statutory Agricultural Exemption ...................................................... 858<br />

C. Exemption of Statutory Marketing Boards ............................................... 858<br />

D. Historical Background: The Special Role of Agriculture ........................ 859<br />

E. The A gricultural Cooperatives ................................................................... 860<br />

F. The Impact of the Exemption ..................................................................... 861<br />

G. A ttempts to A bolish the Exemption ........................................................... 865<br />

H. The Exemption in Light of International Agreements ............................. 867<br />

V. CONCLUSION: IS THERE A JUSTIFICATION FOR AN AGRICULTURAL<br />

E X E M PT IO N ? ........................................................................................................ 87 1<br />

Vice Dean, Faculty of <strong>Law</strong>, Bar Ilan University, Israel; Visiting Professor, Faculty of <strong>Law</strong>,<br />

University of Toronto. E-mail: reicha@mail.biu.ac.il. This article has benefited from the research<br />

assistance of Elad Ofir, and from the comments and suggestions of Professors Adi Eyal, Israel Finkelstein,<br />

Michal Gal, Yoav Kislev, Yael Kachel, Tali Margalit, Joel Trachtman and Michael Trebilcock. I am also<br />

indebted to several people involved in agricultural trade who agreed to answer my questions and share<br />

their experience with me, and among them: Arik Baruchin, Jacob Ben-Dor, Benjamim Korman, and<br />

Gershon Shlissel. The research for the article started with a seminar paper in Hebrew written under my<br />

supervision and encouragement by my student Shlomo Lubin, who passed away shortly after he submitted<br />

the paper. While Shlomo's paper focused on the agricultural exemption in Israeli law, and not on its<br />

comparative aspects like this article, his enthusiasm with the topic was nevertheless a source of inspiration.<br />

May this article be a tribute to his memory.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 843 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

I. INTRODUCTION<br />

Using comparative law as an aid to the legislator can be a very enlightening<br />

exercise, in particular when countries with no experience in a particular field try to<br />

learn from those with more experience than themselves. However, it can also lead<br />

to unfortunate outcomes if the comparison is not done meticulously-viewing the<br />

particular foreign law that is being imitated within its full legal context and social,<br />

political and economic circumstances. Legal transplantation from a "donor"<br />

jurisdiction with a regulatory environment and market structure that is very different<br />

from that of the "recipient" jurisdiction is a recipe for rejection, as has been learned<br />

the hard way by many well-meaning law reformers. Sometimes the reference to<br />

foreign laws is only used as a convenient justification for the adoption of inefficient<br />

or unjust laws in order to conceal the real lobbying efforts and narrow interests that<br />

are behind them. This seems to be the case with the agricultural exemption in<br />

Israel's competition law.<br />

Indeed, special exemptions of the agricultural sector from the full application of<br />

competition rules can be found in many jurisdictions. Most developed countries<br />

consider agriculture as a special sector of the economy requiring intensive<br />

intervention by means of regulation, such as quota systems, price support<br />

mechanisms and protection from imports. These policies are felt strongly in the<br />

international trade arena, where agriculture has always been considered-at least by<br />

the developed countries-as a "special case" not amenable to the regular liberal<br />

trade rules. 1 The refusal of these countries to open up their agricultural sectors to<br />

more international competition, especially for produce from developing countries,<br />

has caused the long impasse in the current Doha Round of multilateral trade<br />

negotiations within the World Trade Organization. Along with these policies, the<br />

developed countries also grant exclusions or partial exemptions to their farmers<br />

from domestic competition law.' Economic, as well as non-economic rationales<br />

(such as the need to preserve rural communities), are claimed to preclude regulation<br />

of the agricultural sector by means of market mechanisms, and to mandate<br />

government regulation of this sector. Inelastic demand, unpredictable and seasonal<br />

supply, and the inability in many cases to store the produce for long time, call for<br />

government intervention and special market organization. Thus, it is argued, rules<br />

founded on and aimed at free and unobstructed competition cannot be applied to<br />

the agricultural sector and hence the need to exempt this sector from antitrust laws.<br />

In the United <strong>State</strong>s (U.S.), the special exemption for the agricultural sector was<br />

enacted as early as in 1922-the Capper-Volstead Act In the European<br />

Community (EC), the exemption is included in the Treaty Establishing the EC, in<br />

Article 36 (ex Article 42), ever since its inception in 1957.' In the United Kingdom<br />

(UK), the Restrictive Trade Practices Act of 1956, which was quite influential in the<br />

1. For a discussion of these claims and their critique as well as of the modern history of the attempts<br />

to regulate international trade in agriculture, see MICHAEL J. TREBILCOCK & ROBERT HOWSE, THE<br />

REGULATION OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE 321-348 (3d ed. 2005).<br />

2. For an overview, see OECD, DIRECTORATE FOR FOOD, AGRICULTURE AND FISHERIES<br />

COMPETITION POLICY AND THE AGRO-FOOD SECTOR (1999).<br />

3. Capper-Volstead Act, 7 U.S.C. §§ 291-292 (1922).<br />

4. Consolidated Version of the Treaty Establishing the European Community, art. 36, Dec. 24, 2002,<br />

2002 O.J. (C 325) 50 [hereinafter EC Treaty].<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 844 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

legislation process of Israel's first competition law in 1959, was also subject to such<br />

an exemption!<br />

Considering these circumstances, it was only natural that Israel's first<br />

competition law-The Restrictive Trade Practices Act, 1959 would also include such<br />

an exemption. Indeed, in the course of the deliberations of the proposed act in the<br />

Knesset (Israel's parliament), when the agricultural exemption was criticized by the<br />

opposition, it was defended by the ruling party through reference to its existence in<br />

other jurisdictions as well. 6 "If other economies, much more developed than our<br />

own and with longer experience with competition law, have chosen to exempt their<br />

agricultural sector from the rules on restrictive agreements - why shouldn't we do<br />

the same?" was in essence the striking argument of the ruling party.<br />

As striking as it may be, the facts are somewhat different. As I will show, none<br />

of the agricultural exemptions in these foreign jurisdictions is nearly as wide as that<br />

adopted-and what is worse, as that maintained until today-by the Israeli<br />

legislature. I will argue that in fact what most probably stood behind the adoption of<br />

this wide agricultural exemption were strong economic interests of the Labor<br />

Movement, which at the time dominated the agricultural sector. As in the EC, the<br />

exemption was part of a general agricultural policy that favored heavy involvement<br />

of the government in this sector and protection of certain farmers' interests, often at<br />

the expense of consumers. What is surprising, however, is that even after this policy<br />

has changed and regardless of the fact that the agricultural sector has been quite<br />

liberalized and opened up to private market forces, the exemption has remained and<br />

managed to withstand several attempts to abolish or amend it.<br />

This paper will discuss the agricultural exemptions in the jurisdictions of some<br />

of the major developed economies-namely, the U.S., the EC and the UK-against<br />

the backdrop of their respective market structures. It will then discuss Israel's<br />

agricultural exemption and its history and compare it to those discussed in the<br />

previous sections. It will show how political forces and narrow economic interests<br />

shaped the wide scope of the exemption and allowed anti-competitive practices to<br />

prevail way into the new era of an open market-based economy. I will then discuss<br />

the possible rationales for a special exemption for the agricultural sector and its<br />

5. The exemption was originally found in the Agricultural and Forestry Association Act, 1962, which<br />

provides that Part I of the Restrictive Trade Practices Act, 1956, shall not apply to certain agreements in<br />

the agricultural and forestry sector. Agricultural and Forestry Association Act, 1962, 11 & 12 Geo. 6, c. 38<br />

(Eng.). It would seem that even before the enactment of the Agricultural and Forestry Association Act of<br />

1962, the sector was partly exempt from the application of the Restrictive Trade Practices Act by virtue of<br />

Section 8(1) thereof, which exempts agreements authorized by any enactment or scheme made under an<br />

enactment. See Restrictive Trade Practices Act, 1956, 4 & 5 Eliz. 2, c. 68, § 8(1) (Eng.), reprinted in LORD<br />

WILBERFORCE, ALAN CAMPBELL & NEIL ELLES, THE LAW OF RESTRICTIVE TRADE PRACTICES AND<br />

MONOPOLIES § 1103 (2d ed. 1966). Since the Agricultural Marketing Act 1958 made provisions for<br />

approved marketing schemes in agriculture, restrictive trade practices implemented in furtherance of such<br />

schemes would seem to fall under this exemption.<br />

6. Divrey HaKnesset, minutes of the 368h session (Dec. 3, 1957) 328. MK Zeev Tzur (Labour Unity-<br />

Poaley Zion party): "Surely you know just like me that also in England the anti-cartel supervision does not<br />

apply to the councils for production and marketing of agricultural produce." (My translation - A.R.).<br />

Similarly during the deliberations in 1959, the exemption was defended several times by reference to the<br />

situation in other countries, such as England, United <strong>State</strong>s, Germany and Austria. While the claims with<br />

regards to England were disputed by the opposition, the fact that the other jurisdictions mentioned had<br />

similar agricultural exemptions as that proposed was not disputed. See Divrey HaKnesset, minutes of the<br />

686h session (July 28, 1959) 33-2739.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 845 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

desirable limits and mechanics. Based on this normative analysis, amendments to<br />

the existing exemptions will be proposed.<br />

II.<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN US LAW<br />

The agricultural exemption in U.S. federal law was granted by Congress<br />

through the Clayton Act of 1916 and the Capper-Volstead Act of 1922.' They were<br />

preceded by many state laws with similar content and objectives -namely to<br />

authorize the existence of agricultural cooperatives and to exempt them from<br />

antitrust liability. 8 The background to the exemption was the atomistic nature of the<br />

farming industry and the inability of individual farmers to bargain on a leveled field<br />

with the few firms that dominated the processing and marketing of agricultural<br />

produce. The farmers were many and scattered, isolated from each other and from<br />

their consumers, making them easy prey for cunning middlemen. The prevailing<br />

situation was described by Baumer et al.:<br />

As the physical and economic distance between farmer and consumer<br />

widened, a growing lack of complete supply and demand information<br />

made it increasingly difficult for individual farmers to make accurate<br />

market predictions before locking themselves into production decisions for<br />

the next harvest. The generally high perishability of agricultural products,<br />

the technological inability to store them for very long, and the absence of<br />

efficient transportation left many individual farmers dependent on one or<br />

a few handlers (processors and distributors). On many occasions the<br />

middlemen abused this power. In an effort to force down prices, the<br />

middlemen could simple threaten not to buy; the prospect of rotten<br />

vegetables or spoiled milk was often enough to make the farmer<br />

capitulate. In the dairy industry, where individual farmers were<br />

dependent on handlers for weighing milk to specify its volume and for<br />

testing its butterfat content, short-changing was a common practice. 9<br />

To countervail the power of the marketing firms and improve their lot, farmers<br />

sought to organize themselves in cooperatives. These organizations were intended<br />

to provide both transportation and marketing services for the farmers, thus<br />

connecting them better with the consumers. This would allow them to obtain fairer<br />

prices for their produce and establish a more efficient and equitable system of<br />

production and distribution. However, such organization of farmers was<br />

problematic from an antitrust standpoint: the cooperation between farmers for the<br />

sake of fixing common prices for their produce and marketing it jointly would seem<br />

to be in violation of the Sherman Act's prohibition of agreements in restraint of<br />

trade.' Indeed, a few cooperatives were found guilty of antitrust violations by the<br />

7. Capper-Volstead Act § 291.<br />

8. See A. Ladru Jensen, The Bill of Rights of U.S. Cooperative Agriculture, 20 ROCKY MTN. L. REV.<br />

181, 191 n.29 (1948) (collecting broad state agricultural cooperative association statutes).<br />

9. David L. Baumer, Robert T. Masson & Robin Abrahamson Masson, Curdling the Competition: An<br />

Economic and Legal Analysis of the Antitrust Exemption for Agriculture, 31 VILL. L. REV. 183, 186-187<br />

(1986).<br />

10. The Sherman Act provides: "Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or<br />

conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several states, or with foreign nations, is declared<br />

illegal...." Sherman Act of 1890, 15 U.S.C § 1.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 846 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

courts." The situation of the agricultural cooperatives in this regard was somewhat<br />

similar to that of the labor unions, in that both were necessary to put the individual<br />

workers/farmers on a level playing field with the more powerful firms that procured<br />

the fruits of their labor, but nevertheless may have been considered in violation of<br />

antitrust laws. Congress therefore came to their rescue through Article 6 of the<br />

Clayton Act of 1916, which provides:<br />

The labor of a human being is not a commodity or article of commerce.<br />

Nothing contained in the antitrust laws should be construed to forbid the<br />

existence and operation of labor, agricultural or horticultural<br />

organizations, instituted for the purpose of mutual help, and not having<br />

capital stock or conducted for the profit, or to forbid or restrain any<br />

individual members of such organizations from lawfully carrying out the<br />

legitimate objects thereof; nor shall such organization, or the members<br />

thereof be held or construed to be illegal combinations or conspiracies in<br />

restraint of trade, under the antitrust laws."<br />

This law provides merely an authorization for farmers to organize themselves in<br />

cooperatives (and to workers in unions) "for the purpose of mutual help."'" As long<br />

as they "lawfully carry[... ] out the[ir] legitimate objects" they cannot be held illegal<br />

under the antitrust laws.' But what type of "mutual help" may they extend to their<br />

members, and what exactly are their "legitimate objects"? In order to clarify that,<br />

and also in order to allow the cooperatives to raise the capital necessary for their<br />

efficient operation, Congress passed the Capper-Vollstead Act in 1922." The Act<br />

identified the legitimate objects of agricultural cooperatives as "collectively<br />

processing, preparing for market, handling and marketing" the agricultural products<br />

of its members for their mutual benefit. 6 Producers of such products were defined<br />

as "Persons engaged in the production of agricultural products as farmers, planters,<br />

ranchmen, dairymen, nut or fruit growers."' 7 While the Act allowed such<br />

cooperatives to issue capital stock, it also imposed several conditions aimed to<br />

ensure that the organization would retain its nature as a true cooperative for the<br />

benefit of its farmer members: (1) that no member of the association should have<br />

more than one vote because of the amount of stock or membership capital he may<br />

own therein; or (2) that the association should not pay dividends on stock or<br />

membership capital in excess of eight percent per annum; and in any case (3) that<br />

the association shall not deal in the products of non-members to an amount greater<br />

in value than such as are handled by it for members.' 8 An association that meets<br />

these conditions is allowed to act cooperatively in setting prices and selling<br />

conditions, and even cooperate with other such associations in setting up common<br />

11. Ford v. Chicago Milk Shippers' Ass'n, 39 N.E. 651 (1895); Reeves v. Decorah Farmers' Coop.<br />

Soc'y, 140 N.W. 844 (1913).<br />

12. Clayton Antitrust Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 12-27 (1914).<br />

13. Id. at §6.<br />

14. Id.<br />

15. Capper-Volstead Act, 7 U.S.C. §§ 291-292 (1922).<br />

16. Id. at §291.<br />

17. Id.<br />

18. Id. § 291. The first two conditions are alternative, and it is enough if a cooperative complies with<br />

one of them. The third is mandatory.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 847 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

marketing agencies-in manners which otherwise would have been considered<br />

illegal under the Sherman Act.' 9<br />

However, the Capper-Vollstead Act also added an important safety valve. It<br />

charged the Secretary of Agriculture with the responsibility of taking action if he<br />

believes that any such association "monopolizes or restrains trade . . . to such an<br />

extent that the price of any agricultural product is unduly enhanced." 2 In such cases,<br />

a decree can be issued against the association that requires it to cease and desist<br />

from such acts. In other words, the exemption is not an unfettered authorization to<br />

engage in anti-competitive behavior to the detriment of consumers. While the<br />

objective was to protect farmers from monopsonist buying power, it was recognized<br />

that this should not be done at the expense of the consumers. Congress was not<br />

willing to grant such immunity to farmers associations-so as to permit them to<br />

develop monopoly power over the consumers-thus substituting one market<br />

distortion for another. As stated in the House Report on the Act:<br />

In the event that associations authorized by this bill shall do anything<br />

forbidden by the Sherman Antitrust Act, they will be subject to the<br />

penalties imposed by that law. It is not sought to place these associations<br />

above the law but to grant them the same immunity from prosecution that<br />

corporations now enjoy so that they may be able to do business<br />

successfully in competition with them. 2<br />

The U.S. courts also considered themselves authorized under the Act, along<br />

with the Secretary of Agriculture, to prevent abuse of the exemption. In Maryland<br />

& Virginia Milk Producers Association v. Unites <strong>State</strong>s, for instance, the U.S.<br />

Supreme Court held that section 2 of the Capper-Volstead Act was not intended to<br />

give the Secretary of Agriculture exclusive jurisdiction over abuses, thereby<br />

excluding any prosecutions under the Sherman Act. 2 ' Thus, when there is anticompetitive<br />

behavior on the part of the agricultural association that unduly enhances<br />

prices, it can be prosecuted by the courts under the existing antitrust laws. The<br />

Maryland & Virginia Milk Producers Association, for instance, which had been<br />

found to attempt to monopolize and entering several anti-competitive agreements,<br />

was ordered to cancel all those contracts and to divest itself of all assets purchased<br />

from a competing dairy. The Supreme Court limited the exemption granted by the<br />

Capper-Volstead Act to the formation of cooperatives and did not extend it to their<br />

anticompetitive activities, such as combining with competitors that are not exempt<br />

cooperatives or using their dominant position to suppress competition with<br />

independent producers and processors. 2 3<br />

19. Id.<br />

20. Id.<br />

21. H.R. REP. No. 24, at 3 (Apr. 27,1921).<br />

22. Maryland & Virginia Milk Producers Ass'n v. United <strong>State</strong>s, 362 U.S. 458, 462-63 (1959). Similar<br />

rulings were made in United <strong>State</strong>s v. Borden Co. 308 U.S. 188, 206 (1939); and in Sunkist Growers v.<br />

Federal Trade Commission, 464 F.Supp 302, 309-310 (1979). It is possible that these rulings reflect some<br />

misgivings about the ability (or willingness) of the Secretary of Agriculture to strike the proper balance<br />

between competition and cooperation, and between the interests of the farmers and those of the<br />

consumers. The Supreme' Court therefore preferred that anti-competitive behavior continued to be<br />

monitored by the antitrust authorities, and not only by the Department of Agriculture.<br />

23. Maryland & Virginia Milk Producers Ass'n, 362 U.S. 472 (stating "the privilege the Capper-<br />

Volstead Act grants producers to conduct their affairs collectively does not include a privilege to combine<br />

with competitors so as to use a monopoly position as a lever further to suppress competition by and among<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 848 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

To sum up: the agricultural exemption in U.S., antitrust law was enacted in<br />

order to correct distortion of competition in the agricultural sector and to allow<br />

farmers to countervail the monopsonist or oligopsonist market power of middlemen.<br />

Hence, it only extends to the formation of cooperatives among farmers, and only<br />

among them 24 and to the legitimate activities of such cooperatives, including joint<br />

processing, handling and marketing. A cooperative must act to the mutual benefit of<br />

its members and divide its profits among them up to a ceiling of eight percent each,<br />

and they are not immune from administrative or judicial supervision where they<br />

engage in anticompetitive activities, such as combinations with competitors, abuse of<br />

dominant position, and mergers.<br />

III. THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN EC LAW<br />

The agricultural exemption in the EC is similar in its contours to the U.S. one.<br />

Here too the main concern seems to be to allow the efficient functioning of<br />

associations of farmers in the form of agricultural cooperatives. In the absence of<br />

such an exemption, these associations could be considered as violating Article 81 of<br />

the EC Treaty. 2 ' The background is the atomistic nature of the agricultural sector,<br />

which was made up of a multitude of small family-run farms, and the urgent need to<br />

encourage the establishment of cooperatives in order to improve the efficiency and<br />

competitiveness of the sector. In addition, and unlike the U.S., the exemption aims<br />

to allow the proper functioning of central governmental policies in the agricultural<br />

sector, mainly the EC's Common Agricultural Policy (CAP), and occasionally<br />

Member <strong>State</strong>s' national policies. In other words, agricultural policy, and in<br />

particular the Treaty's rules on agriculture takes precedence over its competition<br />

policy. 2 6 The exemption was enacted in 1962 by the EC Council in Regulation 267<br />

independent producers and processors."). However, in Alexander v. National Farmers Organization, the<br />

Court of Appeal for the Eighth Circuit held that farmers may, through a single cooperative "or in<br />

combination with other exempt cooperatives, obtain monopoly power in a given market so long as it is<br />

achieved through natural growth, voluntary confederation and without resort to predatory or<br />

anticompetitive practices." Alexander v. National Farmers Organization, 687 F.2d. 1182.<br />

24. These associations may not have members that are not agricultural producers. In re Midwest Milk<br />

Monopolization Litigation held that a co-operative association which wishes to claim Capper-Volstead<br />

exemption must take appropriate action to police its membership so that not even one of its members is a<br />

non-producer (a person who is not engaged in production of agricultural products). In re Midwest Milk<br />

Monopolization Litigation, 510 F.Supp. 381 (WD Mo 1981). The law also provides that a firm that has<br />

both agricultural production activities as well as other activities (such as packing and marketing), may only<br />

be a member to the extent of its agricultural production and in relation to that activity.<br />

25. Article 81 of the EC Treaty prohibits "agreements between undertakings [which could include<br />

individual farmers], decisions by associations of undertakings and concerted practices which ... have as<br />

their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition within the common market,<br />

and in particular those which: (a) directly or indirectly fix purchase or selling prices or any other trading<br />

conditions...." EC Treaty, supra note 4. art. 81. Farmers that organize themselves within cooperatives<br />

normally fix their selling prices and other trading conditions as a natural consequence of pooling their<br />

marketing activity. Instead of each and every one of them competing with each other and taking marketing<br />

and pricing decisions independently, they now cooperate and coordinate their entire marketing activity,<br />

thus in effect restricting competition. That is why an exemption is needed.<br />

26. See EC Treaty. supra note 4: Case C-280/93, Germany v. EU Council, 1994 E.C.R. 1-04973 (finding<br />

that the first paragraph of Article 42 of the Treaty recognizes both the priority of the agricultural policy<br />

over the objectives of the Treaty in the field of competition and the power of the Council to decide to what<br />

extent the competition rules are to be applied in the agricultural sector).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 849 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

pursuant to an express Treaty authorization . 2<br />

provides:<br />

Article 2(1) of the Regulation<br />

Article [81(1)] of the Treaty shall not apply to such of the agreements,<br />

decisions and practices [which relate to production of or trade in the<br />

products listed in Annex [I] to the Treaty] as form an integral part of a<br />

national market organization or are necessary for attainment of the<br />

objectives set out in Article [33] of the Treaty. In particular, it shall not<br />

apply to agreements, decisions and practices of farmers, farmers'<br />

associations, or associations of such associations belonging to a single<br />

Member <strong>State</strong> which concern the production or sale of agricultural<br />

products or the use of joint facilities for the storage, treatment or<br />

processing of agricultural products, and under which there is no obligation<br />

to charge identical prices, unless the Commission finds that competition is<br />

thereby excluded or that the objectives of Article [33] of the Treaty are<br />

jeopardised."<br />

This exception relates only to Article 81 of the EC Treaty. Thus, Article 82, on<br />

the abuse of dominant position, as well as the merger regulations, applies in the<br />

agricultural sector just like in any other sector. Furthermore, even the application of<br />

the exception to arrangements falling under Article 81 has been significantly<br />

curtailed by the restrictive interpretation given by the Commission and the<br />

European Court of Justice (ECJ). 30 It has been held to apply, as stated in the<br />

Regulation, only to the products listed in Annex I to the Treaty, and not to all<br />

agricultural products, as defined in Article 32(1) of the Treaty. 3 ' The first part of the<br />

exemption (national market organization) has only been found to apply once, 32 and<br />

has almost no significance today, since most national market organizations have<br />

been replaced by common organizations set up under EC Council Regulations.<br />

The second part of the exemption (necessary for Article 33 objectives) has been held<br />

to require that all the objectives of Article 33 (i.e. the objectives of the CAP) must<br />

be fulfilled before it can apply, and it is not enough that the restrictive agreement<br />

fulfills the main objectives enumerated in this provision?' The Commission also<br />

requires that it be proven that the agreement is the best means for achieving those<br />

objectives and that there is no other way, less restrictive of competition, to attain<br />

them. 35 As noted by Bellamy and Child, in practice it would appear difficult to show<br />

27. Council Regulation 26/62, Applying Certain Rules of Competition to Production of and Trade in<br />

Agricultural Products, 1959-1962 O.J. SPEC. ED. 129.<br />

28. EC Treaty, supra note 4, art. 36.<br />

29. Council Regulation 26/62, supra note 27, art 2(1).<br />

30. MICHEL WAELBROECK & ALDO FRIGNANI, EUROPEAN COMPETITION LAW 51 (F. Gamet-Pol<br />

trans., 1999).<br />

31. See Case 61/80, Cooperatieve Stremsel-en Kleurselfabriek v. Comm'n, 1981 E.C.R. 851 (holding<br />

that rennet of animal origin, which is a product of first-stage processing and is used in making cheese, was<br />

not deemed to be covered by the exemption); Case T-61/89, Dansk Pelsdyravlerforening v. Comm'n, 1992<br />

E.C.R. 11-1931 (finding that furskins were also outside the exemption's scope, even if they are ancillary to<br />

the production of another product which itself comes under Annex I).<br />

32. Commission Decision 88/109/EEC, 1987 O.J. (C 159) 2; WAELBROEK & FRIGNANI, supra note 30,<br />

at 52.<br />

33. BELLAMY & CHILD, COMMON MARKET LAW OF COMPETITION 827 (4th ed. 1993).<br />

34. Case 71/74 Frubo v. Commission [1975] ECR 563, paras. 24-26; Case C-399/93 Oude Luttikhuis v.<br />

Coberro [1995] ECR 1-4515, para. 25.<br />

35. Frubo, 1975 O.J. (L 237) 16, para. III (3).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 850 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

that an agreement meets this requirement, unless the common organization of the<br />

market expressly contemplates or impliedly permits such an agreement. 36<br />

Thus, the most important and commonly used part of this provision is the<br />

second sentence. Like the U.S. exemption, but unlike the Israeli one, it applies<br />

only to farmers and their associations and not to marketing firms as such. It is,<br />

however, somewhat broader in that it is not limited to the agreements required for<br />

the establishment and proper functioning of the association, but extends also to any<br />

other arrangements between farmers, as well as to arrangements between farmers'<br />

associations, or associations of such associations. There are, however, important<br />

qualifications. Firstly, these associations can only include farmers belonging to a<br />

single Member <strong>State</strong>. A situation where large parts of the Common Market are<br />

dominated by pan-European farmers' associations is thus precluded. Secondly, the<br />

regulation expressly prohibits price fixing (presumably, horizontal). " Finally, as in<br />

the U.S., there is a safety valve in the form of anauthorization of the Commission to<br />

declare the exemption inapplicable if it finds that competition is excluded by the<br />

arrangement in question or that the objectives of Article 33 of the Treaty are<br />

jeopardized. As in the U.S., this authority can also be used by national courts<br />

whenever they are asked to apply the competition rules of the Treaty. 3 They too can<br />

decide-taking into account the relevant case law of the European Court of Justice<br />

(ECJ) and the previous decisions and policies of the Commission-that the<br />

arrangement in question excludes competition, or jeopardizes the objectives of the<br />

CAP, and thus declare it void. 4 "<br />

Based on these principles, the Commission, the ECJ and national courts have<br />

examined various restrictive arrangements in the agricultural sector in order to<br />

determine which ones fall under the exemption, and which ones are overly<br />

restrictive.' In particular, the Commission has withheld the exemption from<br />

36. BELLAMY & CHILD, supra note 33, at 828.<br />

37. Lambros Papadias, Agriculture, in COMPETITION LAW OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY 15-8, 15-<br />

11 (V. Korah ed., 2d ed. 2001). For many years it was unclear whether this second sentence was indeed an<br />

independent exception, or merely an illustration of the first sentence exception. The Commission had<br />

mostly held that it was an independent exception, and this interpretation was confirmed by the Court in<br />

Dijkstra, infra note 40.<br />

38. In other words, it probably does not apply to minimum prices fixed between the farmers and their<br />

cooperatives through which they sell their produce, otherwise it would be virtually impossible for most<br />

cooperative arrangements to benefit from the Art. 2(1), second sentence, exemption. See BELLAMY &<br />

CHILD, supra note 33, at 829; Papadias, supra note 37, 15-12 n.26. Rather, it applies to horizontal price<br />

fixing arrangements between individual farmers, or between two or more farmers' associations, or between<br />

one such association and other independent farmers.<br />

39. Such as those based on art. 81(1) of the EC Treaty, supra note 4,<br />

40. Joined Cases C-319/93, C-40/94 & C-224/94, Dijkstra v. Friesland, 1995 E.C.R. 1-4471 (holding that<br />

if the national court finds that the agreement excludes competition or jeopardizes the objectives of Article<br />

39, it may declare the agreement void pursuant to Article 85(2) of the Treaty if it is incapable under any<br />

circumstances of qualifying for an exemption decision under Article 85(3)).<br />

41. See, e.g., Oude Luttikhuis, Case C-399/93 Oude Luttikhuis v. Coberro para. 25 [1995] ECR 1-4515.<br />

(examining the statute of a milk cooperative that imposed excessive fees on its members upon their<br />

withdrawal from the cooperative, and holding that the cumulative effect of clauses in statutes tying the<br />

members to the association for long periods, and thereby depriving them of the possibility of approaching<br />

competitors, jeopardizes one of the objectives of the common agricultural policy, namely that of increasing<br />

individual earnings in the agricultural sector, and may therefore be prevented from enjoying the<br />

exemption). Likewise, in the matter of a large Dutch dairy milk cooperative (Campina), the exemption<br />

was considered to apply to an exclusive supply obligation, only after the cooperative amended its statutes<br />

so as to allow its members to terminate their membership on three different dates during the year, by<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 851 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

arrangements involving persons other than farmers and their associations, such as<br />

processors and traders of agricultural products, even if concluded with farmers. In<br />

Meldoc it was held that an agreement between five parties, four of which were<br />

farmers' associations and only one of which was a private company, did not fall<br />

under the exemption . The validity of this exception has even been challenged by a<br />

number of traders in agricultural products and their associations who claimed that<br />

the second sentence of Article 2(1) discriminates between producers of and traders<br />

in agricultural products, by excluding the latter from its benefits. The application<br />

was held inadmissible, based on the rule that individuals could not challenge<br />

regulations, only Member <strong>State</strong>s. 3 It has not been challenged ever since, and it is<br />

unlikely that such a challenge could be successful, considering that there are<br />

excellent reasons to distinguish between farmers and traders in this regard."<br />

The distinction has been further strengthened by another important<br />

regulation -Regulation 2200/96 on the common organization of the market in fruit<br />

and vegetables. 45 One of the objectives of this regulation is to strengthen the<br />

position of the producers in the market in the face of "ever greater concentration of<br />

demand", 46 i.e., in the wholesale and retail trading sectors which purchase from the<br />

farmers. To counter this concentration and the market power that comes with it,<br />

"the grouping of supply through [producer] organizations is more than ever an<br />

economic necessity. 4 7 Thus, the Regulation encourages the establishment of such<br />

organizations by giving them a central role in the regulation of the market,<br />

entrusting them with special powers to intervene in the supply and demand side of<br />

the market, and channeling financial support to the farmers through them. They are<br />

authorized to withdraw from the market certain quantities of produce in order to<br />

protect domestic prices. ' This can be done either by purchase and destruction of<br />

produce, or through other means of removal from the market, such as subsidized<br />

exportation. 9 Moreover, Member <strong>State</strong>s may in certain circumstances extend the<br />

rules made by a representative producer organization to non-members of such<br />

organizations located in their region. 0 Thus, rules on production, marketing, quality<br />

standards, environmental protection, and withdrawal of produce 5 may be imposed<br />

giving two years notice, without having to pay any compensation, unless they gave three months notice, in<br />

which a resignation fee of 4% of the price received by them for milk delivered prior to the year of their<br />

withdrawal had to be paid. Commission of the European Communities, XXf' Report on Competition<br />

Policy 1991, at 67-68, paras. 83-84.<br />

42. Commission Decision 86/596/EEC (Meldoc), 1986 O.J. (L 348) 50.<br />

43. Joined Cases 19/62-22/62, F6d6ration Nationale De La Boucherie En Gros et du Commerce en<br />

Gros Des Viandes and Others v. Council of the European Economic Community, ECR 491-92, (English<br />

ed.) 491.<br />

44. Almost all of the special considerations that are invoked in support of the claim that agriculture is<br />

a "special case", such as the atomistic nature of the farming sector, unpredictable growing conditions,<br />

seasonal supply, are only applicable to the farmers, not to the big marketing firms. See further discussion<br />

infra Sect. V.<br />

45. Council Regulation 2200/96, On the Common Organization of the Market in Fruit and<br />

Vegetables, 1996 O.J. (L 297) 1 (EC) (applying to all the fruits and vegetables produced in the EC, except<br />

for potatoes, wine, grapes, bananas, sweet corn, olives and peas and beans for animal feed).<br />

46. Id. at 2, para 7.<br />

47. Id.<br />

48. Id. at 3, paras. 16-17, tit. IV, art. 23.<br />

49. Id. tit. IV, arts. 25, 30, tit. V, art. 35.<br />

50. Council Regulation 2200/96, supra note 45, tit. II, art. 18.<br />

51. Id. Annex III. Non-members may be required to notify the producer organization on their<br />

growing intentions, anticipated tonnages and probable cropping dates. They may be bound by rules on,<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 852 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

on such non-members in order to boost the producer organization's control of the<br />

market, to ensure uniform quality standards and to prevent free-riding by nonmembers.<br />

However, these rules must be notified to the Commission, and if the<br />

Commission finds that they exclude competition in a substantial part of the internal<br />

market, that they jeopardize free trade or that they fall under article 81(1) (i.e., that<br />

they have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of<br />

competition within the common market), it may order the Member <strong>State</strong> to repeal<br />

them. 52 Regulation 2200/96 also provides for the recognition of "inter-branch<br />

organizations," which are organizations made up of representatives of economic<br />

activities linked to the production, trading, and processing of fruits and vegetables.<br />

However the tasks of these organizations is to improve, in general, the production<br />

and marketing of fruits and vegetables by undertaking research and market studies<br />

and improving knowledge and transparency of production and the market." While<br />

Article 20 of the Regulations provides that Article 81(1) of the EC Treaty shall not<br />

apply to agreements of recognized interbranch organizations intended to implement<br />

these type of measures, this exemption only applies if the measures have been<br />

notified to the Commission and the Commission has not found that they are<br />

incompatible with Community rules. The Regulations order the Commission to<br />

declare agreements, decisions, and concerted practices of such organizations as<br />

contrary to Community rules, whenever they may lead to partitioning of markets in<br />

the Community, or may affect the sound operation of the market organization, or<br />

may create distortions of competition which are not essential in achieving the<br />

objectives of the CAP pursued by the organization. 4 Agreements that entail price<br />

fixing, in particular, shall be declared incompatible. 5 These provisions are meant to<br />

ensure that interbranch organizations-i.e., those bodies that include actors other<br />

than the farmers-are not used in a manner that may harm competition, and that<br />

they will be under constant supervision in that regard.<br />

To sum up: while the European Community has a much regulated and heavily<br />

subsidized agricultural sector, 6 it has made efforts to ensure that some competition is<br />

maintained in the sector. It has decided that the agricultural policy, with its strong<br />

emphasis on protecting the income of farmers and ensuring a steady supply of food,<br />

will take precedence over competition rules, but only insofar as is necessary to<br />

achieve the CAP objectives and to protect the farmers. A clear distinction is made<br />

in this regard between farmers and traders, so that only the former are exempt from<br />

some of the competition rules, but are nevertheless under the potential scrutiny of<br />

the Commission and of national courts so as to prevent disproportional distortion of<br />

among others, choice of seeds to be used, specified dates for commencement of cropping, staggering of<br />

marketing, minimum quality and size requirements, and rules of withdrawals of produce adopted under<br />

Article 23.<br />

52. Id. art. 18(5). Similar rules apply to the common organization of raw tobacco (Council Regulation<br />

(EEC) No 2077/92 concerning inter-branch organizations and agreements in the tobacco sector, O.J. L 215<br />

80(1992)).<br />

53. Id. art. 19.1.<br />

54. Id. art. 20.3.<br />

55. Id.<br />

56. The EU common agricultural policy is in the process of several reforms which will make it more<br />

market-oriented and less distorting. Support is shifting from price support to "single-farm payments"<br />

which are decoupled from actual production decisions.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 853 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

competition. The objectives of both Regulations 26 and 2200/96 are to improve the<br />

efficiency of the atomistic farming sector and to strengthen the farmers vis vis the<br />

traders and processors who buy from them. The competition rules are compromised<br />

only insofar as is necessary for that purpose and to achieve other CAP objectives.<br />

IV. THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN THE UNITED KINGDOM<br />

The first enactment in English <strong>Law</strong> imposing judicial supervision over<br />

restrictive agreements was the Restrictive Trade Practices Act of 1956." 7 Part I of<br />

this Act provided that the details of a wide range of restrictive agreements must be<br />

entered on a public register and examined by the Restrictive Practices Court. The<br />

Court then had to decide in the light of the criteria laid down in Section 21 of the<br />

Act whether all or any of the restrictive provisions in those agreements are in the<br />

public interest. 8 A similar, but amended, act was enacted in 1968 bearing the same<br />

name. 9 Art. 8(1) of the 1956 Act exempts agreements authorized by any enactment<br />

or scheme made under an enactment, which could apply also to authorized<br />

marketing schemes in the agro-market. 60<br />

In 1962, the Parliament passed the Agricultural and Forestry Associations Act,<br />

1962 (AFA Act) 6 " which provided that Part I of the 1956 Act shall not apply to<br />

certain agreements in the agricultural and forestry sector (with the fisheries sector<br />

added later 62 ). Here again, as in the U.S. and the EC, the exemption is meant to<br />

enable farmers to organize themselves in cooperatives in order to market and<br />

process their produce and to make collective procurement of the supplies needed to<br />

run their farms. Thus, the AFA Act applies only to associations of persons<br />

occupying land used for agriculture or forestry, in which at least ninety percent of<br />

the voting power is attached to shares held by such farmers or foresters. 63 The only<br />

business, or the principal business, carried on by the association can be marketing or<br />

preparation for market of produce produced by its members on land occupied by<br />

them and used as aforesaid, the supply to its members of goods required for the<br />

production of such produce on such land, and, in the case of a forestry association,<br />

the carrying out of forestry operations for its members on such land.' The type of<br />

agreements that are exempted by the AFA Act are only agreements made by the<br />

members of such associations, or between the association and other persons, for the<br />

purpose of, or in connection with, the marketing or preparation for market by the<br />

association of agricultural produce produced by its members, or for the supply by the<br />

association to its members of goods required for the production of agricultural<br />

57. 4 and 5 Eliz. 2, c. 68. Reprinted in Lord Wilberforce, Alan Campbell & Neil Elles, The <strong>Law</strong> of<br />

Restrictive Trade Practices and Monopolies §1103 (2d ed., 1966).<br />

58. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Guide to Legislation on Restrictive<br />

Business Practices vol. II. United Kingdom (GB) 4 (1976).<br />

59. Restrictive Trade Practices Act, 1968, c. 66 (Eng.).<br />

60. See infra, note 73 and accompanying text.<br />

61. Agricultural and Forestry Association Act, 1962, 11 and 12 Geo. 6. c. 38. ("An act to provide that<br />

certain agreements made by or between members of associations of persons occupying land used for<br />

agriculture or forestry shall be exempted from the application of Part I of the Restrictive Trade Practices<br />

Act, 1956").<br />

62. Agriculture (Miscellaneous Provisions) Act of 1968, s. 44 (Eng).<br />

63. Id. art 1(1) chapeau, para. b.<br />

64. Id. art l(1)(c).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 854 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

produce. Finally, the AFA Act grants powers to the Ministers of Agriculture 65 to<br />

exclude various classes of agreements or various classes of associations by issuing an<br />

order to that effect.6<br />

Such an order was issued shortly after the enactment of the AFA Act, 67<br />

imposing several requirements in relation to the provisions that must be included in<br />

the memorandum or articles of association of these agricultural cooperatives, in<br />

order for them to be eligible for the exemption. These are meant to ensure that the<br />

exemption will be restricted to true agricultural cooperatives, where only farmers are<br />

members and where profits are shared out according to agricultural production. 68<br />

Thus, the profits of the cooperative must be divided among its members in<br />

proportion to the aggregate value of the produce bought from or marketed for each<br />

member; each member can be entitled to one vote only; and the association cannot<br />

market more than one third of the produce marketed by it for non-members of the<br />

association. 69 Furthermore, the association may not be required to sell its produce,<br />

or to buy goods, only to or from a specified person or class of persons. Restrictive<br />

agreements between different associations are also excluded, as are agreements in<br />

relation to various manufactured agricultural products, as specified in a Schedule to<br />

the Order. 70<br />

Along with this exemption for agricultural cooperatives, U.K. <strong>Law</strong> also<br />

provides for special exemptions for approved marketing schemes. Under section 45<br />

of the Agriculture (Miscellaneous Provisions) Act of 1968, 7 ' agricultural marketing<br />

boards may notify their agreements to the appropriate Minister and obtain<br />

exemption from the Restrictive Trade Practices Act if the Minister does not object.<br />

The types of agreements that may be exempt in this way are only agreements<br />

entered into by marketing boards in the exercise of their powers under sections 20(1)<br />

and 36 of the Agricultural Marketing Act 1958,72 agreements that are required for<br />

the implementation of officially approved marketing schemes. 7 However, the<br />

65. Namely, the Minister of Agriculture, Fisheries and Food and Secretaries of <strong>State</strong> respective<br />

concerned with agriculture in Scotland and in Northern Ireland, acting jointly. Id. art. 2(1).<br />

66. Id. art 1(3).<br />

67. The Agricultural and Forestry Associations (Exceptions) Order, 1962, S.I. 1962/1892 [hereinafter<br />

The Order].<br />

68. A common problem with many such cooperatives is that members who once were farmers, but<br />

who have ceased to work in agriculture, continue to be shareholders in the cooperative and demand<br />

dividends from its profits. The Order is meant to prevent this from happening, by precluding the<br />

application of the agricultural exemption from such cooperatives.<br />

69. The Order, supra note 67, § 3.<br />

70. Id. § 4(b)-(c). The excluded products listed in Schedule 1 include: butter, cheese and other milk<br />

products; canned, bottled, sliced, pulped or cooked fruit and vegetables, or such vegetables preserved by<br />

sterilizing, freezing, dehydrating, heat or chemical process; slaughtered cattle, sheep, lambs and pigs and<br />

any parts of such animals; building timber and wood pulp; and wool. Schedule 2 also excludes cars, car<br />

accessories and petrol from the goods that me be purchased collectively by the associations.<br />

71. Agriculture (Miscellaneous Provisions) Act, supra note 62, c. 34.<br />

72. See Agricultural Marketing Act, 1958, 6 & 7 Eliz. 2, c. 47 § 1 (Eng.).<br />

73. Agricultural Marketing Schemes are schemes regulating the marketing of agricultural product by<br />

the producers thereof, which has been approved Minister of Agriculture. They can be submitted by the<br />

representatives of the producers of the product in question in the area to which the scheme is applicable.<br />

See Agricultural Marketing Act, supra note 72, § 1. Under section 20(1) of this Act, marketing boards have<br />

the powers, by virtue of the provisions of such a scheme, to buy the regulated product, to produce<br />

commodities from that product and to sell it or any commodity so produced. They may also determine the<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 855 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

Minister is required under the Act to safeguard the public interest and to consider<br />

the competition law aspects of the agreement and make appropriate directions to<br />

cure any harmful aspects of the agreement.<br />

The Restrictive Trade Practices Act of 1956 was repealed and replaced by the<br />

Restrictive Trade Practices Act of 1976. Under this law, registrable agreements that<br />

were not registered with the authorities were declared void and their parties could<br />

be sued in tort by anyone harmed by them. 7 This new act also granted a special<br />

exemption to various agreements affecting agriculture, fisheries and forestry, which<br />

is essentially identical to the exemption that existed under the previous act. 76 In<br />

2000, all the existing legislation is this field was again repealed and replaced by a new<br />

act-the Competition Act of 1998. 7 ' This law, which is now in force in the United<br />

Kingdom, is modeled on Articles 81 and 82 of the EC Treaty and therefore imposes<br />

a competition regime that is quite similar to that of the European Community. 7 ' The<br />

same applies to the agricultural exemption, which also has been modeled on the EC<br />

exemption. It excludes from the prohibition of Chapter I (parallel to Article 81 of<br />

the EC Treaty) agreements that fall outside Article 81 by virtue of Regulation<br />

26/62. 7 ' The readers are therefore referred to the discussion of the EC exemption in<br />

section III above.<br />

Until this amendment in 1998, the agricultural exemption in force in the United<br />

Kingdom was very similar to that of the U.S., and one may assume that there was a<br />

certain amount of influence on the AFA Act of 1962 by the Capper-Vollstead Act of<br />

1922. Both acts were targeted on farmers' cooperatives and they had rather similar<br />

provisions meant to ensure that the beneficiaries of the exemption would be true<br />

cooperatives of real farmers."' However, the UK exemption was more limited than<br />

its U.S. counterpart: it did not apply to collective processing of the agricultural<br />

produce, but only to' marketing and preparing for market. 8 ' Unlike its U.S.<br />

counterpart, it also did not permit restrictive agreements between different<br />

quantity of the regulated product which any producer may-sell, prescribe maximum or minimum prices,<br />

terms of sale, to whom they may sell, etc. Id § 20(1).<br />

74. See Agricultural Marketing Act, supra note 72, § 20(2).<br />

75. RICHARD WHISH, COMPETITION LAW 94 (1st ed. 1985).<br />

76. Restrictive Trade Practices Act, 1976, c. 34, § 33 (Eng.). See also WHISH, supra note 75, at 120;<br />

NICHOLAS GREEN, COMMERCIAL AGREEMENTS AND COMPETITION LAW: PRACTICE AND PROCEDURE<br />

IN THE UK AND EEC 46 (1986).<br />

77. Competition Act of 1998, c. 41 (Eng.).<br />

78. Even though the United Kingdom is of course a Member <strong>State</strong> of the EC, the EC competition<br />

rules do not apply to commercial activity within the United Kingdom (or another Member <strong>State</strong>) that does<br />

not affect trade between Member <strong>State</strong>s. Such purely domestic activity is subject to U.K. domestic<br />

competition law.<br />

79. Competition Act, supra note 77, sched. 3, para 9. This provision also provides that if the<br />

European Commission decides than an agreement is not excluded from Article 81 by Regulation 26/62, the<br />

exclusion from paragraph 9 of Schedule 3 ceases on the same date. One may wonder why a parallel<br />

authority to deny the exemption from certain harmful agreements or practices has not been given to U.K.<br />

competition authorities.<br />

80. Under both U.K. and U.S. law, each member of the cooperative can be entitled to one vote only,<br />

and the cooperatives are not permitted to deal with more than a certain percentage of non-member<br />

produce (one third in the United Kingdom and one half in the United <strong>State</strong>s). Under both laws, the<br />

association may not pay dividends on stock or membership capital in excess of a certain percentage: 8%<br />

per annum in the United <strong>State</strong>s, and 7% in the United Kingdom.<br />

81. See Agricultural and Forestry Associations Act, supra note 61, § 1:1(c); the Order, supra note 67,<br />

§§ 4(b)-(c) (expressly excluding most processed agricultural products).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 856 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

associations.' On the other hand, it lacked the safety valve of judicial and<br />

administrative supervision by competition authorities that is an important<br />

component of both the U.S. and the EU regimes. Of course, now that the United<br />

Kingdom has adopted an exemption modeled on the EU regime, this component has<br />

been introduced as well.<br />

V. THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ISRAELI LAW<br />

A. Background" Israel's Competition <strong>Law</strong><br />

Israel's current antitrust law, the Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, 1988 (the<br />

"<strong>Law</strong>"), 3 deals with three different types of trade restraints: Restrictive<br />

Arrangements, Mergers, and Monopolies. Restrictive Arrangements are agreements<br />

between two or more parties wherein at least one of the parties restricts itself in a<br />

manner liable to eliminate or reduce business competition." This is usually<br />

understood to include both horizontal and vertical arrangements that may have anticompetitive<br />

effects. Article 2(b) of the <strong>Law</strong> has been interpreted by the Israel<br />

Supreme Court 85 as creating irrebuttable presumptions regarding the anticompetitive<br />

effects of certain types of restrictive provisions, such as those relating to price,<br />

profits, division of the market and the quantity, quality or type of assets or services<br />

in the business.' Israeli law thus has a wide range of arrangements that are<br />

prohibited per se. A restrictive arrangement is prohibited unless it obtains the<br />

approval of the Antitrust Tribunal, or an individual exemption by the Antitrust<br />

Authority, or if all restraints in the arrangement are exempt in accordance with a<br />

block exemption issued by the Antitrust Authority. 7 The first two types of<br />

exemptions require the filing of a petition by the parties to the arrangement, unlike<br />

the third one, where the arrangement is automatically exempt if it fulfills all the<br />

conditions of the block exemption. However, the <strong>Law</strong> also includes a list of<br />

statutory exemptions (in Article 3), which grants quite broad exemptions to various<br />

types of arrangements by declaring them to be not restrictive. 88 These exemptions<br />

are usually unconditional and leave no discretion to any of the antitrust authorities<br />

82. The Order, supra note 67, § 3.<br />

83. Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, 1988, 42 L.S.I. 135, (1987-88).<br />

84. See id. § 2(a).<br />

85. CA 6222/97 Tiv'ol (1993) Ltd. v. The <strong>State</strong> of Israel et al. [1998] IsrSC 52(3) 145.<br />

86. Article 2(b) provides:<br />

Without derogating from the generality of the provisions of subsection (a), an arrangement<br />

involving a restraint relating to one of the following issues shall be deemed to be a restrictive<br />

arrangement:(1) The price to be demanded, offered or paid; (2) The profit to be obtained; (3)<br />

Division of all or part of the market, in accordance with the location of the business or in<br />

accordance with the persons or type of persons with whom business is to be conducted; (4) The<br />

quantity, quality or type of assets or services in the business.<br />

87. Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 83, § 4.<br />

88. The opening sentence of Article 3 of Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 75, provides:<br />

"Notwithstanding the provisions of section 2, the following arrangements shall not be deemed restrictive<br />

arrangements ..<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 857 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

to withdraw the exemption in cases of abuse or when severe anticompetitive<br />

consequences ensue.89<br />

B. The Statutory Agricultural Exemption<br />

One of these statutory exemptions is the agricultural exemption (Article 3(4)).<br />

It extends to:<br />

An arrangement involving restraints, all of which relate to the growing or<br />

marketing of domestic agricultural produce of the following kinds: fruits,<br />

vegetables, field crops, milk, honey, cattle, sheep, poultry or fish, provided<br />

all parties thereto are growers or wholesale marketers of such produce; the<br />

above provision shall not apply to goods manufactured from such<br />

agricultural produce[.] 9 °<br />

Thus, the exemption extends to practically all types of agricultural products, but<br />

only to the produce itself, and not to goods manufactured from such produce. It<br />

exempts any types of arrangements, whether horizontal or vertical, from the<br />

prohibition against restrictive arrangements, but not from the other prohibitions and<br />

provisions of the <strong>Law</strong>. Mergers between companies in the agricultural sector are not<br />

exempt from the <strong>Law</strong>'s provisions subjecting them to the prior approval of the<br />

Antitrust Authority, nor are they exempt from its chapter on monopolies.<br />

Unlike the U.S. Capper-Volstead Act and the EC exemption discussed above,<br />

this provision exempts not only the growers of agricultural products, but also the<br />

wholesale marketers of such products, even if these marketers are not involved in<br />

the growing or production of such products. Also, the provision grants a broad<br />

exemption to all types of arrangements made in relation to the growing and<br />

marketing of agricultural products, not only to collective arrangements between<br />

farmers, as in the U.S. exemption. Finally, the exemption is absolute and is not<br />

subject to supervision or possible withdrawal by the authorities or the courts in cases<br />

of harmful anticompetitive behavior.<br />

C. Exemption of Statutory Marketing Boards<br />

Another statutory exemption that has been important for the agricultural sector<br />

in Israel and in the past virtually insulated it from any type of competition is found in<br />

Article 3(1) which exempts arrangements "involving restraints, all of which are<br />

established by law." The agricultural policy since the fifties was based on central<br />

planning of both production and marketing and strong regulatory involvement. For<br />

89. The Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 83, provides that "the [Minister of Industry and<br />

Trade] may, by order with the agreement of the Minister of Agriculture and the approval of the Knesset<br />

Economic Committee-add or detract categories of agricultural produce .. " Id. § 3(4). This authority,<br />

that has never been used, could probably not be used against specific cases of abuse or severe harm to<br />

competition, since it authorizes only to delete (or to add) types of products, and not types of behavior or<br />

specific parties, from the exemption. It appears thus more like a mechanism to determine the definition of<br />

the types of products that will be considered as "agricultural products" in case of uncertainty in this regard.<br />

The onerous legislative process that is required in order to make such an order also supports this<br />

understanding and helps to explain why it has never been used.<br />

90. Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 83, art. 3(4).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 858 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

this purpose statutory marketing boards were established for the various agricultural<br />

sectors, such as the Citrus Fruit Board, the Vegetables Board, the Flowers Board<br />

and the Milk Board. " ' These bodies were authorized by law to allocate production<br />

quotas, set prices and regulate marketing of the products within its mandate. They<br />

also established an export monopoly- Agrexco Ltd.-with exclusive rights to export<br />

Israeli agricultural produce to other countries. The members of the marketing<br />

boards were representatives of the producers, of the marketing firms, of the<br />

government and of the consumers, with the producers having at least 50% of the<br />

membership (and often more) and hence effective control of the boards. These<br />

arrangements, which otherwise would be incompatible with the prohibition against<br />

restrictive arrangements, were thus exempt under Article 3(1.) as restraints<br />

"established by law." There is almost no parallel to such elimination of competition<br />

in the U.S. system, but it is quite similar to the European system of central planning<br />

in some of the agricultural sectors, especially in the past.<br />

D. Historical Background: The Special Role of Agriculture<br />

To understand the agricultural exemptions in Israel's antitrust law, one must<br />

turn to the history of agriculture in the young state and of the political and economic<br />

role that it has played in the Zionistic movement. The agricultural sector has been<br />

pivotal in the resettlement of the Land of Israel ever since the end of the 19 h<br />

century, in the defense of its borders and in the development of its economy.<br />

Indeed, working in agriculture was perceived as a major means in achieving the<br />

greatest of Zionist ideals-the return of the nation to its land and redemption of the<br />

land of the forefathers. 9 " It represented the very essence of the Zionistic ethos of<br />

conquering the desolation, greening the desert, and building a new type of "strong<br />

and healthy" Israeli attached to the land, different from the detached, ghetto-like<br />

Jew of the exile. 93 The prevalent form of cooperative settlement of the land, in the<br />

form of Kibbutzim and cooperative Moshavim," was also the embodiment of the<br />

socialist ideology that permeated much of the Zionistic movement in those years.<br />

Thus, it was only natural that the agricultural sector would have a special status<br />

in relation to other economic sectors and enjoy special treatment from the<br />

authorities. After the establishment of the <strong>State</strong> in 1948, agriculture became even<br />

more important and central to its national strategy of settling the land and taking<br />

control of its territories. Security concerns and the conflict with its Arab neighbors<br />

required settlement along the long borders and in remote areas with sparse<br />

population. There was an urgent need to ensure a rapid increase in the supply of<br />

food to the growing population, as Jews were flocking into the land from Europe and<br />

North-Africa. Agriculture also played an important role in providing work for all<br />

the new immigrants, whether as settlers or as employees of the farmers. And there<br />

91. While the Milk Board is not formally a Statutory Board, but rather a private corporation<br />

established pursuant to a government decision, in the past its director or deputy director had statutory<br />

authority to establish production quotas for the milk sector. Such quotas would therefore come under the<br />

exemption of Article 3(1) of the Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>.<br />

92. YAIR AHARONI, THE ISRAEL ECONOMY: DREAMS AND REALITIES 202 (1991).<br />

93. ALEX BEIN, THE RETURN TO THE SOIL: A HISTORY OF JEWISH SETTLEMENT IN ISRAEL (trans.<br />

Israel Schen, 1952).<br />

94. For an explanation of these forms of settlement, see infra note 98.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 859 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

was an ideological-political affinity between the financing bodies (the Ministry of<br />

Agriculture and Rural Development, and the Jewish Agency) and the settlement<br />

movements, such as the Kibbutz movements and the Moshav movement. They were<br />

all members of the Socialistic-Zionistic movement. 9 Indeed, Israel is unique in the<br />

world in having almost all of its agricultural settlements organized under the<br />

umbrella of political movements. 96 To receive allocation of land and means of<br />

production, farmers had to be organized by a settlement movement, all of which<br />

were affiliated with one or another political party."<br />

In later years, when industry took over as the more important foundation of the<br />

young economy and agriculture was losing its centrality (in particular because of the<br />

limited availability of water supply), it became difficult to change policies and<br />

abolish special rights and privileges acquired by the agricultural sector. It had<br />

established a very strong and coherent lobby with much power within the political<br />

parties. Its central role in the Zionistic ethos, as well as its importance for national<br />

security, continued to have a significant effect. This power was used to obtain<br />

government subsidies and import protection and to secure the political interests<br />

entrenched in the existing institutional arrangements.<br />

E. The Agricultural Cooperatives<br />

Unlike the United <strong>State</strong>s, where the agricultural exemption was adopted as a<br />

counterweight to the marketing firms in order to allow the farmers to organize<br />

themselves in cooperatives, in Israel agricultural marketing was organized in<br />

cooperatives almost from the outset. 98 At the time of the enactment of the<br />

Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong> in 1959 (which first introduced the agricultural<br />

exemption and on which the 1988 <strong>Law</strong> is based), these cooperatives were already<br />

major forces in the market.<br />

95. Yonathan Shapiro, The Historical Origins of the Israeli Democracy, in ISRAELI DEMOCRACY<br />

UNDER STRESS 65-80 (Larry Diamond and Ehud Sprinzak eds., 1993).<br />

96. Aharoni, supra note 92, at 207.<br />

97. For a strong critique of this situation, see Ezra Sohar, ISRAEL'S DILEMMA: WHY ISRAEL IS<br />

FALLING APART AND How To PUT IT BACK TOGETHER 210-225 (1989). The political affiliation with a<br />

"settlement movement" was crucial not only for the establishment of the village itself, but also in order to<br />

get allocation of water and production quotas. These were allocated according to movement affiliation<br />

pursuant to agreements between the political parties. Individual private farms were almost non-existent<br />

until some 20-30 years ago. Since then, the strength of the political parties and their affiliated settlement<br />

movements in agricultural settlement has been in decline.<br />

98. Not only marketing, but most of the Jewish agricultural settlement in Israel was organized in<br />

cooperative structures. These took four main forms: 1. Workers' Moshav, a village with some 60-150<br />

farmers organized in a cooperative for the purpose of selling their agricultural produce and common<br />

purchase of all needs, both for private purposes and for the agricultural production; 2. Kibbutz, a large<br />

cooperative settlement of some 80-250 families based on common ownership of all property, private and<br />

productive, common work by everyone and equal sharing of all income. All members eat in a common<br />

dining room, where the food is prepared by a common kitchen, and all needs are supplied by common<br />

storerooms according to rules decided by the Kibbutz assembly and secretariat; 3. Cooperative Moshav, a<br />

hybrid of the former two: the production and marketing is common and proceeds are shared out equally, as<br />

in a Kibbutz, but each family runs their own household individually, as in a Workers' Moshav; 4. Private<br />

Farms, organized in different forms, but where each farmer is the owner of his own farm and runs his<br />

business privately. 6 ENCYCLOPAEDIA HEBRAICA 837-838 (1957) (Hebrew). However, even in the noncooperative<br />

agricultural sector, many farmers became members of large marketing cooperatives for the<br />

purpose of marketing their produce or exporting it.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 860 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

One of them in particular, Tnuva-Cooperative Center for the Marketing of<br />

Agricultural Produce Ltd. (Tnuva), incorporated the entire Labor Movement<br />

settlement, i.e. the agricultural production of all of the Kibbutzim and Moshavim,<br />

and held some 75% of the market in many products. 99 Its involvement spanned the<br />

entire spectrum of agricultural production, from milk, meat and fish, to vegetables<br />

and fruit. Another cooperative, Tene, incorporated many private farmers and held<br />

market shares of between fifteen percent and twenty percent in some products.'"<br />

These cooperatives were very powerful and politically well connected.'' Tnuva, in<br />

particular, was considered as part and parcel of the Labor Movement and the Labor<br />

party, which was in power uninterruptedly since the establishment of the <strong>State</strong> in<br />

1948 until the electoral victory of the Likud party in 1977. The ruling party until<br />

then thus saw it as its natural mandate to protect the interests of Tnuva and the<br />

agricultural establishment, while the opposition from the right tried unsuccessfully to<br />

prevent such protection. That this was the background to the adoption of the<br />

agricultural exemption is very clear from the parliamentary discussions in connection<br />

with this exemption.' 2 This explains why the exemption is not limited to<br />

arrangements between farmers, but extends to marketers, as well. Also, at the time,<br />

the marketers and the farmers were almost the same, since it was the farmers, in<br />

particular those of the Kibbutzim and cooperative Moshavim, who controlled the<br />

largest marketing firms, i.e., the cooperative marketing organizations. As a result of<br />

this exemption, Tnuva could enter any type of restraining arrangements, both<br />

horizontal, with competing marketing firms, as well as vertical, with its suppliers, the<br />

farmers, and (in the past) with its downstream customers, the retailers.' Examples<br />

of problematic vertical agreements are those prescribing exclusivity of supply, i.e.<br />

that the farmer is precluded from selling any of his produce to any other marketer,<br />

or that the retailer is precluded from carrying products of any other marketing firm.<br />

F. The Impact of the Exemption<br />

As a result of the heavy regulation and lack of competition, the Israeli<br />

agricultural market was characterized by very high marketing margins, with huge<br />

differences between the consumer price and what the farmer actually received for<br />

99. Id. at 947.<br />

100. Divrey HaKnesset, Minutes of the 368 ' h Session (Dec. 3, 1957), 325 (speech of MK Benjamin<br />

Avniel, Herut Party); 6 ENCYCLOPAEDIA HEBRAICA, supra note 98, at 832 (according to this source, Tene<br />

was a cooperative marketing organization established to serve so-called "Rasco settlements", which were<br />

private middle-class agricultural settlements established between 1935-1945 by the Rasco Settlement<br />

Company). In the mid-fifties, while Tnuva controlled the marketing of some seventy-two percent of the<br />

Jewish agricultural produce, Tene together with three other cooperatives marketed another 12% of this<br />

produce. Id. at 947.<br />

101. On the power of the agricultural lobby and its sources, see AHARONI, supra note 92, at 212.<br />

102. Divrey HaKnesset, Minutes of the 368h Session (Dec. 3, 1957), DK (1957) 325-28 (argument<br />

between MK Benjamin Avniel of the market-oriented Herut Party and MK Zeev Tsur of the ruling<br />

Labour Unity-Poaley Zion party); DK (1959) 2733 (argument between MK Benjamin Avniel and MK<br />

Shmuel Shoresh of the coalition).<br />

103. It should be noted that the original agricultural exemption that was found in the Restrictive<br />

Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong> of 1959 did not limit the exemption to wholesale marketers. Thus restrictive<br />

agreements between a wholesaler like Tnuva and retail marketers would also come under the exemption.<br />

This was changed in 1963. when the law was amended so that all parties to a restrictive arrangement had to<br />

be either wholesale marketers or farmers.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 861 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

his produce.'04 In citrus products, for instance, the individual grower received only<br />

about fifteen percent of the price paid by the final consumer. 5 Under the marketing<br />

board system, in most sectors production quotas were allocated by the boards, and<br />

marketing was allowed only through "licensed marketers." Exportation could only<br />

be done through the monopoly Agrexco Ltd. or through the marketing boards.<br />

Thus, with much of the marketing heavily regulated and subject to quotas and price<br />

arrangements that were strictly enforced, the impact of the agricultural exemption<br />

itself was probably limited, although not insignificant,'0 6 that is, until the market was<br />

deregulated and opened up to private market forces.<br />

Towards the end of the eighties, the Israeli agricultural sector found itself in a<br />

serious crisis. The many boards and cooperative organizations involved in<br />

purchasing, production and marketing had grown into inflated and inefficient<br />

bureaucracies. Cheap financing and subsidized water led to imprudent choices of<br />

production venues. In addition, some irresponsible investment and loan decisions by<br />

the cooperative purchasing organizations caused heavy losses that put unbearable<br />

debts on all of its members. When interest rates went up, farmers were unable to<br />

repay their debts. The government was forced to step in to prevent total collapse of<br />

many Kibbutzim and Moshavim. This was done by legislation that provided for debt<br />

adjustments and partial relinquishment by the banks. 7 The crisis, along with the<br />

switch to market-oriented ideologies, convinced the policy makers that serious<br />

reforms were needed in the agricultural sector.<br />

This process started with the decision in 1991 to allow private firms to engage in<br />

the marketing of citrus fruits, both for export and in the domestic market. The<br />

process continued with other fruits and vegetables, and culminated with the<br />

dissolution of most of the marketing boards in favor of privatization and freer<br />

competition.9' Thus, for the first time, the Agrexco export monopoly was faced with<br />

competition.<br />

104. STATE OF ISRAEL, MINISTRY OF FINANCE, ECONOMIC POLICY 2007, EXPLANATORY<br />

MEMORANDUM TO THE BUDGET LAW OF 2007, 19.<br />

105. AHARONI, supra note 92, at 213.<br />

106. For instance, it would seem that if not for Section 3(4), the collective agreement by all of the<br />

marketing boards to establish a single export monopoly (Agrexco) may also have been problematic under<br />

the Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>. See ITZCHAK YAGUR, RESTRICTIVE TRADE PRACTICES LAW 345<br />

n.44 (2002) (Hebrew).<br />

107. <strong>Law</strong> on Arrangements in the Family Agricultural Sector, 1992, S.H. 118.<br />

108. In 2003, all of the marketing boards in the fruit, vegetable and flower sectors (the Fruit Board,<br />

the Citrus Fruit Board, the Vegetables Board, and the Flowers Board) were amalgamated into one board<br />

(the Plants Board), and their establishing legislation was repealed and substituted by one law: the Plants<br />

Board <strong>Law</strong> (Production and Marketing), 1973, S.H. 310 (as amended by the <strong>Law</strong> for the Improvement of<br />

the Israeli Economy (Statutory Amendments for Achieving the Budget and Policy Targets for FYs 2003 &<br />

2004), 2003)). The law transferred most of the regulatory powers of the Boards to the Minister of<br />

Agriculture, thus taking away these powers from the farmers and their organizations, and giving it to the<br />

government. It, in turn, used these powers much more sparingly than had previously be done by the<br />

Boards, thus in essence, ushering in much more competition to the sector. The reform was unsuccessfully<br />

challenged by the boards and many of the farmers' associations before the High Court of Justice. For the<br />

judgment, see HCJ 4885/03 Org. of the Chicken Growers, et al. v. Gov't of Israel 59(2) 14. The economic<br />

reform of the marketing in the agricultural sector is described in detail in the judgment. In July 2006, the<br />

Minister of Agriculture, Shalom Simchon, decided to reevaluate the need for the Plants Board, and<br />

therefore refused to sign the order allowing the Board to impose charges on the farmers, thus in essence,<br />

freezing its ability to function. Press Release, Ministry of Agric. (July 24, 2006), available at<br />

http://www.moag.gov.il.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 862 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

As a result of these developments, the anticompetitive impact of the exemption<br />

has increased. There is evidence of several attempts of cartelization, some of which<br />

may have been successful. For instance, for many years Tnuva, which was the coowner<br />

of two of the largest poultry slaughterhouses, had an arrangement with four<br />

of the other poultry slaughterhouses whereby it would be the sole marketer of all the<br />

produce of these six producers."' ° Due to this arrangement, Tnuva could control a<br />

major share of the poultry and turkey-meat market, and prevent any competition<br />

between these major producers. Pursuant to the agreement, Tnuva sold the produce<br />

of all the slaughterhouses at the same prices, paid them the same commissions, and<br />

determined their production quotas." ° The policy in this regard, was agreed at<br />

regular weekly meetings between the parties. For years, Tnuva claimed that its<br />

actions were exempt under the Agricultural Exemption of Article 3(4),"' and only in<br />

2003 did the Antitrust Authority decide to challenge this position in court, arguing<br />

that packed meat was a manufactured product and therefore fell outside the<br />

exemption. This legal disagreement on the scope of the exemption was never<br />

resolved by the Court, because the parties eventually decided themselves to<br />

discontinue the arrangement and pursue independent marketing." 2 Thus, the Courtorder<br />

requiring its discontinuance was issued with the consent of all the parties<br />

involved." 3<br />

Interviews by the present author with some senior actors in the agricultural<br />

market have revealed that the exemption has enabled cartels and other restrictive<br />

arrangements in several agricultural sectors. For instance, in the potato sector,<br />

following the abolition of the statutory quota regime, there were several attempts to<br />

create cartels, to coordinate prices and share markets between the marketers, not all<br />

of whom were also potato growers. ' 4 Many of these arrangements were<br />

unsustainable and therefore quite unsuccessful, as often is the case with cartels,<br />

109. Press Release, Antitrust Auth., Antitrust Court Issues Agreed Decision to Discontinue<br />

Restrictive Agreement between Tnuva and Several Slaughterhouses (Nov. 24, 2003), Publication No.<br />

3018918.<br />

110. Id.<br />

111. Already in 1995 the question whether this cartel was exempt under Section 3(4) came up in legal<br />

proceedings before the Antitrust Tribunal in connection with a proposed acquisition by Tnuva of one of<br />

the slaughterhouses. CA 2/94 Tnuva v. Antitrust Auth. [1995], ch. D. In those proceedings, Tnuva<br />

appealed the Authority's refusal to approve the merger and one of its arguments was that it fell under the<br />

Agricultural exemption. Because of judicial economy, the Tribunal did not rule on the question whether<br />

the exemption could have any impact on mergers or on whether the product in question was considered an<br />

agricultural or manufactured product. However, it did mention the restrictive agreements in the sector,<br />

raised serious doubts on their legality and called upon the Authority to challenge them in court, so that its<br />

position on the proper limits of the exemption could be established.<br />

112. However, in Appeal (Jerusalem) 1/00 Food Club v. Antitrust Supervisor, the Antitrust Tribunal<br />

expressed its opinion that slaughtered chickens were within the exemption, and did not amount to<br />

"manufactured agricultural products". Nevertheless, the slaughterhouses could not come within the<br />

exemption because they were not "marketers". See also CrC (Jer) 960/05 Gen. Dir. of the Antitrust Auth.<br />

v. Avi Margalit [2006] (pending appeal to the Supreme Court in Cr. A. 7128/06).<br />

113. HCJ 8009/03 Antitrust Supervisor v. Tnuva Coop. Ctr. for the Mktg. of Agric. Produce Ltd.<br />

[2003].<br />

114. Information obtained from Mr. Benjamin Korman, a former CEO of Yevulim, Sh. Sharon Ltd.;<br />

and Mr. Gershon Shlissel, who at the time served as the business manager of Kibbutz Alumim, one of the<br />

large producers and marketers of potatoes. Yevulim is a large private wholesale marketer of agricultural<br />

products. It is not a cooperative of farmers [hereinafter Korman & Shlissel].<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 863 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL VOL. 42:843<br />

because of the Prisoners' Dilemma involved for each participant."' There were<br />

however several successful arrangements to eliminate surpluses, so as to keep the<br />

domestic price of potatoes high. This was achieved either by destruction of this<br />

surplus or through its subsidized export.' 1 6 In either case, funds were needed to pay<br />

the growers whose produce was destroyed or exported. These funds were<br />

successfully collected from all of the marketers and thus the surplus was removed<br />

from the market." 7 Similar arrangements were achieved and executed in the carrot<br />

sector and in the banana sector." 8 Moreover, in the potato sector the largest<br />

marketing firm (an agricultural cooperative" 9 ), is known for binding its growers with<br />

very restrictive agreements, which precludes them from selling any of their produce<br />

(whether potatoes or other produce marketed by the firm) through any other<br />

outlet. 2° A grower who wants to leave the cooperative may be severely fined by<br />

losing all of its invested capital. A similar arrangement can be found in the wine<br />

growing sector, where members of the largest and oldest wine production<br />

cooperative, the Carmel Winery,"' are legally required under the by-laws of the<br />

cooperative, to sell all of their produce to the winery, and can be punished by high<br />

fines if they fail to do so.' 22<br />

In the milk sector, there is a strict regime of production quotas, minimum<br />

prices, barriers to entry, surplus elimination and other restrictive arrangements. It is<br />

supervised and enforced by the Milk Sector Board, which is not a statutory body, but<br />

rather a corporation that is run by representatives of the dairy farmers, the milk<br />

production plants and the government.' 23 Some of the arrangements in this sector<br />

115. The reason cartels are faced with the Prisoners' Dilemma is that while each participant in the<br />

game can gain much from colluding with the others, she can gain even more from cheating, for example,<br />

from a situation where all the other parties to the cartel abide by it except for herself. See KEITH N.<br />

HYLTON, ANTITRUST LAW: ECONOMIC THEORY AND COMMON LAW EVOLUTION 68-69 (2003).<br />

116. Such export subsidies may be problematic under various international trade agreements. See<br />

generally Multilateral Agreements on Trade in Goods, Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral<br />

Trade Negotiations, Apr. 15, 1994. Whether or not they are is a complicated question that is outside the<br />

confines of the current article.<br />

117. In order to collect the funds, the marketers received assistance from the Plants Board, which<br />

collected them and paid them out according to the criteria that had been agreed upon by the members of<br />

the cartel. While the Plants Board is a statutory body entrusted to regulate the plants and vegetable sector,<br />

it does not have the authorization to initiate on its own such an arrangement as described here. Only the<br />

Minister of Agriculture can do so by issuing regulations. See The Plants Board <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 83. Thus,<br />

in the absence of such regulations, the arrangement could not have been legally achieved and executed<br />

without the agricultural exemption. Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 83, § 3(4).<br />

118. See Korman & Shlissel, supra note 114. In the carrot sector, a fund was established in order to<br />

subsidize export of surpluses, so as to remove them from the domestic market. In the banana sector, a<br />

successful cartel was established between the producers of about 80% of the produce.<br />

119. The Maon District Settlements Agricultural Cooperative for Regional Development Ltd., is a<br />

cooperative of Kibbutzim, Moshavim and other farmers in the western Negev area. The firm is the owner<br />

of the brand-name "Uncle Moshe" and the biggest exporters of potatoes to Europe. See<br />

www.dodmoshe.co.il.<br />

120. See Korman & Shlissel, supra note 114.<br />

121. Its official name is Societe Cooperative Vigneronne des Grandes Caves Richon le Zion &<br />

Zichron Ya'acov Ltd. See The Ups and Downs of Israel's Most Famous Winery, ISRAEL WINES, Sept. 2005,<br />

http://www.israelwines.co.il/ArticlesEng/Article.asp?ArticlelD=1349&CategorylD=82.<br />

122. Information obtained from Mr. Jacob Ben-Dor, business manager of Moshav Beit Yatir, a<br />

member of the cooperative.<br />

123. Amiram Cohen, The Milk Producers Threaten to Exacerbate their Struggle Against the<br />

Privatization of Tnuva: Threaten to Create Blocking Minority, HA'ARETZ, Nov. 5, 2006 (Hebrew), available<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 864 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

are sanctioned under the Israel Dairy Sector Planning <strong>Law</strong>, 1992124, but many others<br />

can only exist by virtue of the Agricultural Exemption."2 Here too, the large<br />

marketing firms often use their market power to tie the dairy farmers to them and to<br />

prevent sales to other firms.' Similarly, the fish growers are organized in a<br />

voluntary organization which for some time marketed all of their produce for them,<br />

and wherein lately agreements on minimum prices were concluded. 27 These<br />

arrangements could not be legally maintained without the Agricultural Exemption.<br />

The courts have usually interpreted the exemption narrowly, thus breaking up<br />

many cartels in the agricultural manufacturing sectors. 2 8 Recently, the Jerusalem<br />

District Court convicted the participants of a cartel in the frozen vegetable sector.'<br />

It ruled that frozen vegetables are industrially processed products and hence fall<br />

outside the exemption. However, for the production and marketing of the<br />

agricultural produce itself the exemption has remained intact.<br />

G. Attempts to Abolish the Exemption<br />

One would expect that the same policy considerations that led the government<br />

to dissolve the marketing boards would lead it to abolish, or at least limit, the<br />

provision that prevents full application of competition rules to the agricultural<br />

sector. And indeed the government, especially under the leadership of the more<br />

free-market oriented Likud party, has attempted several times to do so, with the<br />

strong encouragement of the Antitrust Authority and the consent of the Ministry of<br />

Agriculture. The first attempt was in 2002, when the Government decided to limit<br />

the exemption to growers, and exclude marketers. " ' The second was in 2003, when<br />

the same decision was taken again,' and in 2004 the same ritual was repeated for<br />

the third time.1 2 All these attempts, however, have failed as the bills in this regard<br />

have been met with staunch opposition in the Knesset. Strangely, the opposition has<br />

come from both Opposition and Coalition parties. 3 Analysis of the discussions<br />

indicates that the Knesset members in doing so seemed to be convinced that they<br />

http://www.haaretz.co.il/hasite/pages/ShArtPE.jhtml?itemNo=562985&contrassID=2&subContrasslD=6&<br />

sbSubContrasslD=0.<br />

124. Sefer Hachukim, 1992 S.H. 139; amendment: Sefer Hachukim, 2002 S.H. 135.<br />

125. Yael Kachal & Israel Finkelstein, Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>s in the Agricultural Sector in<br />

Israel, United <strong>State</strong>s and the European Union: A Comparative Analsis 7 (May 2005) (Hebrew) available at<br />

http://departments.agri.huji.ac.il/economics/previous-2005.html.<br />

126. Tnuva, for instance, extends long-term loans to the farmers under beneficial terms, under the<br />

condition that they sell all their produce to it. Should a farmer choose to switch to a competing firm, he is<br />

required under the loan agreement to return the loan immediately with significantly higher interest than if<br />

he had remained with Tnuva.<br />

127. Kachal & Finkelstein, supra note 125, at 8.<br />

128. See, e.g., CC 1633/94 Y. Katz Agric. Supply Ltd. v. HaLulan, Small Farms Agric. Coop., [19981.<br />

129. CrC (Jer) 960/05 Gen. Dir. of the Antitrust Auth. v. Avi Margalit [2006] (pending appeal to the<br />

Supreme Court in Cr. A. 7128/06).<br />

130. Government of Israel, Decision of July 30, 2002, approving the economic policy for FY 2003.<br />

131. Government of Israel, Decision of Sept. 15, 2003, approving the economic policy for FY 2004.<br />

132. Legislative bill amending the Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, 2003, ch. 13 art. 60.<br />

133. See DK (2005) 396 (Economy Committee Member Daniel Benlulu: "Mr. Chairman, today we are<br />

going with the Opposition. We proposed [to take it out of the <strong>Law</strong>] not MK Avshalom Vilan [from the<br />

Opposition; Member of left-wing Meretz Party].").<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 865 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

were acting for the protection of the farmers. 3 1 What they did not seem to realize is<br />

that by maintaining the exemption for the marketing firms they are in effect harming<br />

the farmers by empowering the marketing firms to coordinate purchasing policies vis<br />

A vis the farmers. This can allow them to exercise oligopsonistic market power<br />

against the farmers and dictate prices to their detriment. It is possible that there are<br />

lobbying efforts by powerful firms such as Tnuva and industrial food conglomerates<br />

that are behind this voting pattern. It may also be the power of inertia and habit<br />

that cause the politicians to continue to identify farmers' interests with those of<br />

former agricultural cooperatives, even though this is no longer the case. Not only is<br />

Tnuva no longer the only or even the major player in the agricultural marketing<br />

sector, but it has also ceased to be a true cooperative of farmers, since many of its<br />

shareholders have long ago abandoned farming, it is run like any other corporate<br />

conglomerate, and recently it was sold off to a global private equity group.' 36<br />

Lately, the Government has again decided to try to limit the exemption.<br />

However, this time a much less ambitious amendment is being proposed, namely to<br />

exclude from the exemption wholesale marketing firms that are connected to retail<br />

marketers (by holding five percent or more of their stock). "7 The reasons given are<br />

that an examination of the excessive differences between the producer and the<br />

consumer prices in the fruit and vegetable market shows that much of it originates in<br />

the retail phase. The government analysts suggest that it may be a result of the<br />

mounting concentration in the retail market, as a result of the growing market power<br />

of the large food retailers. 38 Since most of these retailers have set up their own<br />

wholesale marketing firms, they are able to take advantage of the exemption of<br />

134. Id. See, e.g., the statement by MK Rochama Avraham, of the Likud Party: "This <strong>Law</strong> is too<br />

complicated and I must admit I need to study it... I think we have to separate it from the Arrangements<br />

<strong>Law</strong> ... and besides I am for the agriculture and if it may harm the farmers at this time, even if only a little,<br />

we have to stand firm and not allow it." When the Chairman of the Committee, MK Amnon Cohen,<br />

explained the Committee's decision to take it out from the <strong>Law</strong> before the Knesset plenary, he said:<br />

"[S]ince we are dealing with a topic that it has been said may have wide repercussions, including harming<br />

the farmers, and thereby [harming] the agriculture in Israel, the Committee has decided to request that the<br />

bill should be separated." Once this amendment is separated from the main law, it gets postponed to some<br />

undefined date in the future and, in practice, never reaches the floor.<br />

135. While industrial food conglomerates are of course not included under the exemption, if the large<br />

marketing firms bring the prices down, the food conglomerates that process agricultural produce will also<br />

be able to purchase this produce for less. It also seems that the farmers' organizations are afraid of the<br />

"slippery slope" syndrome, and believe that once the exemption it limited, it may get abolished altogether.<br />

136. These original shareholders, which represent a large part, perhaps even a majority, of the current<br />

shareholders, have been pushing for the payment of dividends from the cooperative's profits and for a<br />

corporate reform, under which Tnuva will be converted into a regular commercial corporation and part of<br />

it will be sold to a financial investor. Their efforts were successful and in November 2006, following an<br />

international auction, the control of Tnuva was sold off for over $1bn to Apax Partners Worldwide LLP, a<br />

British buyout firm. See http://www.foodanddrinkinsight.com/file/41872/apex-triumphs-in-tnuva-biddingwar.html<br />

137. Economic Policy 2007, supra note 104, at 19. The proposal uses the term "Interest Holder" and<br />

refers to the Companies <strong>Law</strong>, 1999 for the definition of the term. There it is defined as five percent<br />

holding (art. 1). According to the proposal, both if the wholesale marketer has such an interest in a retail<br />

marketer, or that the retail marketer has such an interest in the wholesale marketer, such a marketer will<br />

be excluded from the exemption.<br />

138. In 2005, one of the food retail chains, Clubmarket, which had attempted to challenge the<br />

dominant position of the two other large chains, collapsed and went into bankruptcy. It was eventually<br />

sold by the receiver to one of these two chains, causing a significant increase in the concentration in the<br />

food retail market. See Anat Roeh & Chaim Bior, Court Okays Supersol-Clubmarket Deal, Lock, Stock<br />

and Collective Work Agreement, HA'ARETZ<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 866 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

wholesale marketers from the antitrust rules,' 39 even though they are in essence<br />

retailers. They can therefore leverage their market power in the retail sector against<br />

the growers to their detriment and to the detriment of consumers who are forced to<br />

pay higher prices for fruits and vegetables.<br />

Indeed, there is no reason to doubt the wisdom of precluding the retail chains<br />

from taking advantage of an exemption that was not meant for them. However, this<br />

official explanation does not explain why other wholesale marketers can continue to<br />

take advantage of the exemption, allowing them to collude against the farmers and<br />

use their market power to gain excessive rents from both farmers and consumers.<br />

The most likely explanation of the fact that the more extensive amendment of the<br />

exemption has not been attempted at this time is that the Government has resigned<br />

itself to the reality of the strong agricultural lobby, and is therefore trying now a<br />

more limited amendment. Eventually, however, even this limited amendment was<br />

opposed by members of the "agricultural lobby" and failed to get approved by the<br />

Knesset. 140<br />

H. The Exemption in Light of International Agreements<br />

Israel's agricultural exemption appears to be problematic from another<br />

perspective as well, namely that of International Trade <strong>Law</strong>. The problem stems<br />

from the fact that the exemption applies only to "the growing or marketing of<br />

domestic agricultural products.''<br />

4. This means that imported agricultural products<br />

are not covered by the exemption and may not benefit from them. Such<br />

discrimination between domestic and imported products, which did not exist under<br />

the previous law,' 42 would seem to be inconsistent with several international trade<br />

agreements to which Israel is a party, in particular the General Agreement on Tariffs<br />

and Trade (GATT).' 43 Article 111:4 of GATT provides:<br />

139. See Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 83, § 3(4).<br />

140. See Protocol of the Finance Committee of the Knesset, Dec. 24, 2006, on the Economic<br />

Arrangements <strong>Law</strong> (Statutory Amendments to Achieve the Budget Targets and the Economic Policy for<br />

FY 2007), 5767-2006, www.knesset.gov.il/protocols/data/rtf/ksafim/2006-12-24-05.rtf. As can be seen from<br />

the protocol, the main opponent of the amendment of the agricultural exemption was MK Avshalom<br />

Vilan, from the left-wing Meretz Party, who serves as the Chairman of the Agricultural Lobby in the<br />

Knesset, and formerly served as the Secretary-General of one of the three Kibbutz movements<br />

("HaKibbutz Ha'Artzi"). He was joined by several Knesset members from the Labor Party. Eventually,<br />

the amendment was separated from the Economic Arrangements <strong>Law</strong> and hence never reached the<br />

Knesset for a final reading, just as happened with all the previous attempts to limit the exemption.<br />

141. Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 83, art. 3(4).<br />

142. The previous 1959 Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong> also had an agricultural exemption (in<br />

Section 8), but it was not confined to domestic produce. Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, 5719-1959, 13 LSI<br />

159 (1958-59) (Isr.).<br />

143. General Agreement of Tariffs and Trade, Oct. 30, 1947, 61 Stat. A-11, 55 U.N.T.S. 194<br />

[hereinafter GATT]. It should be pointed out, that even though agriculture is considered a "special case"<br />

in international trade law, the "agricultural exemptions" in this field do not have any bearing on the case at<br />

hand. These "exemptions" are embodied in the Agreement on Agriculture, which is one of the WTO<br />

agreements. This agreement deals with the generally high tariffs and subsidies in the agricultural sector. It<br />

provides for progressive reduction of these tariffs and subsidies (both domestic support and export<br />

subsidies). Sanitary and phytosanitary import measures that affect agriculture are dealt with in the<br />

Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures. See Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and<br />

Phytosanitary Measures, Art. 2.1, Final Act Embodying the Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral<br />

Trade Negotiations, Apr. 15, 1994, 33 I.L.M. 1125 (1994) [hereinafter SPS Agreement], available at<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 867 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

The products of the territory of any contracting party imported into the<br />

territory of any other contracting party shall be accorded treatment no less<br />

favorable than that accorded to like products of national origin in respect<br />

of all laws, regulations and requirements affecting their internal sale,<br />

offering for sale, purchase, transportation, distribution or use."'<br />

In Korea - Various Measures on Beef, the Appellate Body of the World Trade<br />

Organization (WTO) explained that there are three elements of a violation of this<br />

provision: (1) That the imported and domestic products at issue are "like products";<br />

(2) that the measure at issue is a "law, regulation, or requirement affecting their<br />

internal sale, offering for sale, purchase, transportation, distribution or use"; and, (3)<br />

that the imported products are accorded "less favorable" treatment than that<br />

accorded to like domestic products."" 14<br />

The first element, "like products," is not an issue in this case because the legal<br />

provision in question-Article 3(4) of the Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>-extends<br />

the exemption to a wide range of products provided that they are domestic<br />

agricultural products. It is not hard to find a wide range of foreign agricultural<br />

products that are similar in all relevant aspects to the domestic products that<br />

currently are enjoying the benefits of this exemption and therefore fulfill the<br />

requirement of "like products," but nevertheless are precluded from enjoying the<br />

same benefits just because they are not domestic. As for the second element, clearly<br />

Israel's Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong> is a "law", and it would also seem that its<br />

prohibition against restrictive agreements is a law that affects "the internal sale,<br />

offering for sale [or] purchase" of imported agricultural products. Pursuant to this<br />

prohibition-that only applies to imported agricultural products, but not to like<br />

products of domestic origin-firms that market these products in the Israeli market<br />

are not permitted to make cartels and other restrictive agreements with their<br />

competitors, suppliers or customers in relation to these products. Such agreements,<br />

by definition, affect the internal sale, offering for sale or purchase of such products:<br />

they may fix their prices, divide the areas or type of customers to which they are to<br />

be sold, or coordinate other trading conditions, such as credit terms. Clearly, then, a<br />

law prohibiting such agreements affects "their internal sale, offering for sale,<br />

purchase, transportation, distribution or use."' 46<br />

Also the third element of "less favourable treatment" seems to exist here, even<br />

by virtue of the mere fact that imported products are subject to more stringent rules<br />

than like products of national origin. While in Korea - Various Measures on Beef,<br />

the Appellate Body stressed that different treatment in itself is not necessarily<br />

inconsistent with Article 111:4, however, if the different treatment is also "less<br />

http://www.wto.org/English/docs-e/legal-e/15-sps.pdf. However, none of these agreements provides any<br />

exemption from the disciplines of GATT art. III discussed in the text above.<br />

144. GATT, supra note 143, art 111:4.<br />

145. Appellate Body Report, Korea-Measures Affecting Imports of Fresh, Chilled and Frozen Beef,<br />

para. 133, WT/DS161/AB/R (Dec. 11, 2000) [hereinafter Korea -Various Measures on Beef].<br />

146. In Canada-Certain Measures Affecting the Automotive Industry, a WTO Panel held that "the<br />

ordinary meaning of 'affecting' implies a measure that has 'an effect on' and thus indicates a broad scope of<br />

application." Panel Report, Canada-Certain Measures Affecting the Automotive Industry, para. 10.80,<br />

WT/DS139/R (Feb. 11, 2000). In Korea-Various Measures on Beef, the Appellate Body considered a<br />

Korean measure that established a dual retail distribution system for the sale of beef as a "measure<br />

affecting the internal sale etc." of such products. Under this system, imported beef had to be sold either in<br />

specialized stores selling only imported beef or, in the case of larger department stores, in separate sales.<br />

See Korea - Various Measures on Beef, supra note 145.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 868 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

favorable", then the element is fulfilled.' 7 This should be assessed by examining<br />

whether the measure modifies the conditions of competition in the relevant market<br />

to the detriment of imported products.1 8<br />

If marketing firms could enter into cartels and other restrictive agreements in<br />

relation to domestic agricultural products, and thus benefit from higher prices and<br />

better sales conditions, but are precluded from making the same agreements in<br />

relation to like imported products, then the latter products will be less profitable and<br />

less attractive to them. Such difference in treatment would therefore modify the<br />

conditions of competition in the relevant market to the detriment of imported<br />

products. 9 On the other hand, under accepted WTO jurisprudence, there is no need<br />

to show that this difference in treatment actually leads to protection of domestic<br />

production. As held by the Appellate Body in EC-Bananas III:<br />

Article 111:4 does not specifically refer to Article 111:1. Therefore, a<br />

determination of whether there has been a violation of Article 111:4 does<br />

not require a separate consideration of whether a measure 'afford[s]<br />

protection to domestic production."" °<br />

Article 3(4) of Israel's Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong> may also be problematic<br />

under some of its bilateral free trade agreements.'' For instance, the prohibition of<br />

"measures having equivalent effect"-equivalent to the effect of quantitative<br />

restrictions on imports-which is included in most of these trade agreements,' 2 may<br />

147. See Korea-Various Measures on Beef. supra note 145, para. 135. See also Report of the Panel,<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s -Section 337 of the Tariff Act of 1930, para. 5.11, L/6439.<br />

148. Korea Appellate Body Report, supra note 145, para. 137. See also Appellate Body Report,<br />

Japan- Taxes on Alcoholic Beverages, 16, WT/DS8/AB/R (Oct. 4, 1996) (quoting GATT, supra note 143,<br />

Art. 111(1-2)); Panel Report, Japan-Measures Affecting Consumer Photographic Film and Paper, para.<br />

10.379. WT/DS44/R (Mar. 31, 1998).<br />

149. One could of course make the argument that due to the fact that restrictive agreements between<br />

the marketing firms in relation to imported products are not allowed, competition on the consumer market<br />

is bound to go up, and prices for consumers will come down. This then would actually improve the<br />

competitive conditions of imported products, in relation to like domestic agricultural products, and not<br />

vice versa. This argument can be dismissed based on two reasons: 1. If real competition exists between<br />

domestic and imported products, domestic products are bound to come down as well. There is nothing in<br />

the <strong>Law</strong> that prevents the marketing firms from lowering the prices of domestic produce, in order to<br />

compete better. 2. The situation on the consumer level of the market may be as it may, but on the<br />

wholesale level imported agricultural produce clearly suffers from less favourable treatment by the <strong>Law</strong>.<br />

This situation is likely to lead to a competitive disadvantage of imported produce in relation to domestic<br />

produce, in that the wholesale firms have good reasons to prefer the latter.<br />

150. Appellate Body Report on European Communities - Regime for the Importation, Sale and<br />

Distribution of Bananas, WT/DS27/AB/R, para. 216 (Sept. 9, 1997). This ruling rejects, therefore, the<br />

approach of the Panel on Canada - Certain Measures Concerning Periodicals, where the Panel examined<br />

whether a measure at issue "afford[ed] protection to domestic production." Panel Report, Canada-<br />

Certain Measures Concerning Periodicals, para. 5.38, WT/DS31/R (Mar. 14, 1997).<br />

151. There are also bilateral agreements that include National Treatment obligations similar to<br />

GATT Article III. See, e.g., Article 4.1 of the Free Trade Agreement between the Government of Canada<br />

and the Government of the <strong>State</strong> of Israel. Free Trade Agreement between the Government of Canada<br />

and the Government of Israel, 1997 Can. T.S. No. 49. There are some exceptions to this prohibition that<br />

are listed in Annex 4.1 of the Agreement, but the measure discussed here is not one of them. Id.<br />

152. See, e.g., Euro-Mediterranean Agreement Establishing an Association between the European<br />

Communities and their Member <strong>State</strong>s, of the one part, and the <strong>State</strong> of Israel, of the other Part, art. 16,<br />

2000 O.J. (L147) 3 [hereinafter EC-Israel Association Agreement]; Agreement on the Establishment of a<br />

Free Trade Area between the Government of Israel and the Government of the United <strong>State</strong>s of America,<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 869 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

preclude this type of discriminatory treatment. The phrase "measure of equivalent<br />

effect" has been interpreted by the European Court of Justice ever since the famous<br />

Dassonville case' 5 3 as including "all trading rules enacted by member <strong>State</strong>s which<br />

are capable of hindering, directly or indirectly, actually or potentially" trade between<br />

states. While this interpretation relates to the term as it appears in the Treaty<br />

Establishing the European Community' 54 and is not formally binding on states<br />

outside the EC and in relation to other agreements, it is nevertheless instructive as to<br />

the possible meaning of the term. In any case, if it could be shown that the more<br />

stringent competition rules that apply to imported agricultural products actually<br />

serve to hinder, obstruct or reduce the importation of such products, this would<br />

certainly prove that the prohibition has been violated. Article 3(4) would also seem<br />

to be in violation of the competition rules that are included in the EC-Israel<br />

Association Agreement, which provides that "all agreements between undertakings,<br />

decisions by associations of undertaking and concerted practices, which have as their<br />

object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition" shall be<br />

"incompatible with the proper functioning of the Agreement."' 55 One could argue<br />

that by permitting such restrictive agreements in the agricultural sector, but not<br />

allowing the same for imported products, the <strong>Law</strong> in effect causes restriction and<br />

distortion of competition in this sector. 5 6<br />

The problem described above is mostly connected to the exemption of the<br />

marketers, and not of the producers, of the agricultural products. The reason for this<br />

is that the producers of imported agricultural products are by definition located in<br />

foreign countries. They, therefore, are in any case outside the territorial scope of<br />

Israel's antitrust law and are not in need of its agricultural exemption. Since most<br />

developed countries have their own agricultural exemption for producers, they are<br />

likely to benefit from such exemptions. It would therefore be much harder to make<br />

a case for a violation of GATT Article 111:4 if all that Article 3(4) of Israel's<br />

Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong> did was to exempt growers of domestic agricultural<br />

products. For that to be possible there would have to be an attempt on Israel's part<br />

to apply its antitrust law extra-territorially to foreign growers, something which is<br />

extremely unlikely both legally and politically.' 57 Thus, if my proposal to abolish the<br />

art. 4, 24 I.L.M. 653 (1985); Agreement Establishing a Free Trade Area between the <strong>State</strong> of Israel and the<br />

Republic of Turkey, art. 7, KAV 1322. available at http://www.moital.gov.il/NR/exeres/0740267B-3FAD-<br />

4875-A445-95416E4793F6.htm The provisions of the two latter agreements are confined to "new"<br />

measures. Id. One could therefore argue that since the exemption is not new, the prohibition does not<br />

apply. However, this argument may only be used for trade agreements concluded after 1988 (when the<br />

<strong>Law</strong> was enacted), because in the previous law of 1959, the agricultural exemption was not confined to<br />

domestic produce. Since the agreement with the United <strong>State</strong>s was concluded in 1985, this defense could<br />

not be used. Also, in the EC agreement, the prohibition is not confined to "new" measures. Id.<br />

153. Case 8/74, Procureur de Roi v. Dassonville, 1974 E.C.R. 837, 851.<br />

154. EC Treaty, supra note 4, art. 28.<br />

155. EC-Israel Association Agreement, supra note 152, art. 36.<br />

156. This argument is strengthened by the fact that Article 36:4 expressly excludes agricultural<br />

products from the prohibition that appears in paragraph 1(iii) of Article 36. This paragraph refers to<br />

public aid which distort or threatens to distort competition. This implies that the other paragraphs of<br />

Article 36(1) (including the one that prohibits restrictive agreements between undertakings) do apply to<br />

agricultural products.<br />

157. Application of one <strong>State</strong>'s law, in particular criminal law, on citizens of another <strong>State</strong> for acts<br />

committed within the territory of that other <strong>State</strong> is usually considered contrary to International <strong>Law</strong> and<br />

an infringement on that <strong>State</strong>'s territorial sovereignty. Occasionally, however, some states, such as the<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s and the EC, claim the right to apply their competition laws on acts committed outside their<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 870 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

agricultural exemption insofar as it applies to marketers were accepted, the problem<br />

under international law would also be solved.<br />

V. CONCLUSION: IS THERE A JUSTIFICATION FOR AN AGRICULTURAL<br />

EXEMPTION?<br />

The rationale of competition law is that competition is good for the economy<br />

and for the consumers and that attempts by firms to restrict competition should be<br />

prevented by law. Competition is seen as the pillar of modern market economies<br />

and the foundation of capitalism, in that it stimulates innovation, encourages<br />

efficiency, and drives down prices. According to microeconomic theory, in general,<br />

no system of resource allocation is more efficient than competition. It causes<br />

commercial firms to develop new products, services, and technologies, which in turn<br />

gives consumers greater selection and better products. The greater selection<br />

typically causes lower prices for the products compared to what the price would be if<br />

there was no competition. While competing firms have a clear interest in restricting<br />

competition to capture monopoly or monopsony rents at the expense of consumers<br />

or suppliers, respectively, the general efficiency of a society requires that such<br />

strategic behavior is prevented so that competition is preserved.<br />

The question that has to be asked is whether there is anything peculiar to the<br />

agricultural sector that justifies departure from this rationale in countries where it is<br />

followed and implemented in all other economic sectors? One such peculiarity<br />

which, as we have seen, seems to have motivated legislators in the U.S., EU and the<br />

UK to grant certain exemptions to farmers, is the atomistic nature of the farming<br />

industry, which often is made up of family-run farms and other relatively small units<br />

of production. This nature is sometimes contrasted with the concentration in the<br />

agricultural marketing and processing sector. Under such conditions-and under the<br />

assumption that countries have an interest (usually, for non-economic reasons) in<br />

preserving these traditional characteristics of the farming industry-there may be<br />

efficiency and distributive justice rationales for cooperation and coordination among<br />

farmers. Efficiency may be promoted by allowing farmers to organize in<br />

cooperatives so as to rationalize their production, transportation and distribution<br />

processes, provide the farmers with up to date information on market trends,<br />

consumer preferences and agricultural know-how, and to establish common brands<br />

and quality standards. 5 ' Such cooperation may also help put the farmers on a more<br />

equal footing with marketing and processing firms, thus allowing a more efficient<br />

bargaining outcome and preventing oligopsonistic rents in the pockets of the latter.<br />

Organization into cooperatives in effect serves as an alternative to corporate<br />

mergers of small farmers into larger farming conglomerates, which in any case would<br />

territory if such acts have a negative effect on their market. Such claims are highly controversial and quite<br />

rare, in particular among smaller countries.<br />

158. The setting of quality standards can be seen as a means to overcome market failure due to lack of<br />

sufficient information among consumers at the point of sale on the quality of the produce. While both in<br />

the EU and the United <strong>State</strong>s there is legislation enabling farmers' organizations to establish quality<br />

standards, it is not clear why such a function should be entrusted exclusively with farmers-whose interests<br />

do not necessarily coincide with those of the consumers-and not with an independent standard setting<br />

organization, where along with the farmers, consumers and government representatives also have a say.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 871 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

not be prevented under most merger regimes. 9 Preserving the livelihood of familyrun<br />

farms would also be more in line with distributive justice, considering the<br />

generally hard living conditions of small farmers in relation to large marketing firms.<br />

Finally, by preserving family farms and traditional farming communities, we would<br />

also be serving communitarian values as well as contributing to the protection of the<br />

environment.' 6°<br />

However, such rationales could only be invoked to permit small or perhaps<br />

medium-sized farmers to organize into cooperatives. It certainly cannot justify<br />

exempting marketing firms as such from the regular competition rules. And even as<br />

far as farmers are concerned, the exemption can be justified only under certain<br />

conditions, similar to those described. Thus, an exemption must be granted by a<br />

very fine-tuned instrument that sets appropriate conditions for the right to invoke it.<br />

Such conditions should include provisions to ensure that the cooperative does not<br />

obtain market power (for instance, that the exemption is limited by a maximum<br />

market share of the cooperative), that only small- or medium-sized farms or<br />

agricultural producers can benefit from the exemption, that the cooperative only<br />

incorporates active farmers and deals almost exclusively with the produce of its<br />

members; and that the cooperative is managed by and for the benefit of its members.<br />

One should also ensure continuous supervision by competition authorities and<br />

courts, who ought to be authorized to withdraw the exemption whenever it is used to<br />

excessively restrict competition or distort markets.<br />

Another peculiarity of the agricultural sector is the relatively inelastic demand<br />

for its produce, the unpredictable and seasonal supply, and the inability in many<br />

cases to store the produce for long periods of time. However, these problems can<br />

hardly be solved by merely allowing coordination between growers. If these<br />

problems exist, and to the extent that they cannot be overcome by regular market<br />

mechanisms, they would require government intervention and special market<br />

organization. If, for instance, there is justification for regulation of production<br />

quantities and allocation of quotas, surely this cannot be effectively done by<br />

voluntary agreements between the producers. Such quotas would need to be<br />

imposed and enforced on all of the producers in the market, in particular on those<br />

producers who have an incentive to produce more than their allocated quotas and<br />

would therefore never join a voluntary arrangement that restricts their ability to do<br />

so. Even if agreement could be reached between all the producers, because of the<br />

Prisoners' Dilemma involved, it would be a very fragile agreement that would be<br />

159. Since the acquisition of each individual farm usually falls under the prevailing value thresholds of<br />

merger supervision, unless the acquiring firm has acquired a market share that gives it a dominant position<br />

in the market, the merger will not be precluded by most merger regulations. Under Israeli law, for<br />

instance, a merger falls under merger supervision only if it fulfills at least one of three conditions: 1. If the<br />

merger will lead to a market share of over 50%; 2. That the joint turnover of the merging entities is more<br />

than 150 Million Shekel and that each entity has a turnover of at least 10 Million Shekel (1 Million<br />

Shekel=approx. US$ 230,000); 3. That one of the merging entities is already a monopoly (Article 17 of the<br />

Act). In the EU, a "Community Dimension" is required, which means that the combined aggregate<br />

worldwide turnover of all the undertakings concerned is more than 5 Billion, and that this turnover of<br />

each of them is at least 250 Million. Council Regulation 139/2004, EC Merger Regulation, art. 1(2), 2004<br />

O.J. (L 24) 6 (EC). An alternative criteria requires a lower worldwide threshold of "only" 2.5 Billion, a<br />

turnover of 100 Million in each of at least three EU Member <strong>State</strong>s, and individual turnovers of 25<br />

Million in those three Member <strong>State</strong>s, and worldwide turnover of at least 100 Million each. Id. art. 1(3).<br />

Clearly, any farm acquisition would fall under this threshold.<br />

160. In many countries, preservation of farms and agricultural land is one of the major factors that<br />

prevent large-scale urbanization and gradual elimination of green areas and natural habitats.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 872 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE AGRICULTURAL EXEMPTION IN ANTITRUST LAW<br />

extremely hard to enforce. Therefore, states that have reached the conclusion that<br />

they want to impose such special centralized market organization have done so by<br />

means of mandatory regulation in one form or another.'' Such regulation, to the<br />

extent that it is in conflict with existing competition rules, would usually be exempt<br />

by a general exemption of statutory mandated arrangements 62 and not by a specific<br />

exemption for restrictive agreements in the agricultural sector. In any case, such<br />

specific market regulation, which often has the effect of almost eliminating<br />

competition altogether, ought to be pursued with utmost caution, after extensive<br />

study of the market and only after the regulators are completely convinced than no<br />

other market-based solution is possible. Certainly, there is no place for a<br />

comprehensive elimination of all competition in the agricultural sector, as can be<br />

learnt from the Israeli (and the EU) experience.<br />

In light of this analysis, all of the agricultural exemptions discussed in this<br />

article would require some amendments. The U.S. exemption, found in the Capper-<br />

Volstead Act of 1922, could benefit from some more clear-cut market-share caps,<br />

which would ensure that the exemption is not utilized whenever it leads to marketpower<br />

by the parties to the arrangement. In this connection, it should be kept in<br />

mind that the Act permits not only agreements between the farmers and their<br />

respective cooperatives, but also agreements between various cooperatives,' 63<br />

something that could lead to cartelization of the market. The same applies to the<br />

EU exemption, which also permits arrangements between farmers' associations, or<br />

associations of such associations," 6 ' but fails to set market-share caps or other clear<br />

limitations. Since both the U.S. and EU exemptions, unlike the U.K. and Israeli<br />

exemptions, extends not only to joint marketing and preparation for market (sorting,<br />

packaging etc.), but also to processing, there is also a risk that the exemption will be<br />

used by industrial food producers, owned by various farmers cooperatives, to restrict<br />

competition between them. While such problematic developments could be<br />

thwarted by the authorities or the courts if they discovered them, it would seem<br />

much more effective to define expressly the scope of the exemption so as to remove<br />

doubts and to make prosecution and civil proceedings in case of abuse easier.<br />

Clearly defined rules also create a more predictable business environment which is<br />

an important component of an efficient market. As for the U.K. exemption (prior to<br />

its harmonization with the EU regime in 1998), it lacked the safety valve of judicial<br />

and administrative supervision by competition authorities and the courts, to ensure<br />

that the exemption is not used to restrict competition and distort markets<br />

excessively.<br />

This last shortcoming (lack of supervision) is also one that the Israeli exemption<br />

suffers from. In addition, there can be no justification for an extension of the<br />

exemption to marketing firms. The exemption should therefore be amended so that<br />

it is confined to farmers. It should be modeled upon the previous UK exemption, so<br />

that only farmers' cooperatives are exempted under similar conditions as provided<br />

161. For example, in the EC through the Common Agricultural Policy, which provides for an<br />

extremely regulated market in the agricultural sector. In the United Kingdom, mainly prior to its joining<br />

the EC, through the Agricultural Marketing Act of 1958, supra note 72, and in Israel through the various<br />

marketing boards legislation, as discussed above.<br />

162. Examples include § 3(1) of Israel's 1988 Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 83, and §<br />

8(1) of the UK Restrictive Trade Practices Act of 1956, supra note 5.<br />

163. See supra note 19 and accompanying text.<br />

164. Provided that they belong to a single Member <strong>State</strong>. See supra note 37 and accompanying text.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 873 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:843<br />

for therein. In fact, in order to achieve a well-balanced and fine-tuned exemption in<br />

line with the principles elaborated above, it would be best if the exemption was<br />

removed from the <strong>Law</strong> itself, and incorporated into a new block exemption. Such<br />

exemptions can be issued by the General Director of the Antitrust Authority, with<br />

the consent of the Advisory Exemptions and Mergers Committee, and are the more<br />

appropriate instruments for granting fine-tuned exemptions to specific sectors or to<br />

certain categories of agreements. 16 ' They are often restricted by market-share caps<br />

and other sector-specific conditions. Another advantage of using a block exemption<br />

is that it remains in force for a maximum period of five years only, after which it can<br />

be renewed as is or in an amended formula, if it is still deemed necessary. This<br />

mechanism ensures periodical reviews of the exemption, of the structure of the<br />

market to which it applies, and of its continuing necessity. Also, by taking the<br />

exemption out of the law once and for all, required amendments to it will no longer<br />

be blocked by the agricultural lobby. Instead, the exemption will be designed and<br />

amended by the Antitrust Authority, in conjunction with the Advisory Committee,<br />

which is made up of independent civil servants and antitrust experts. 1 ' 6 Finally, by<br />

using a block exemption, instead of a statutory exemption as is done today, we<br />

would achieve the safety valve that today is missing. Under Article 15A(g) of the<br />

<strong>Law</strong>, the General Director has the authority to withdraw the exemption from a<br />

specific restrictive arrangement, and would do so presumably if she finds that the<br />

competition is being excessively restricted to the detriment of consumers or other<br />

market participants.<br />

165. See art. 15A of Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 83. According to this provision, a<br />

block exemption can be issued, provided that all of the following conditions are met:<br />

(1) That the restraints in the restrictive arrangement do not reduce competition in a<br />

considerable share of the market affected by the arrangement, or that they may reduce the<br />

competition in a considerable share of the market, but do not result in a substantial reduction<br />

of the competition in such market.<br />

(2) That the objective of the arrangement is not the reduction or elimination of competition,<br />

and that the arrangement does not include any restraints which are not necessary in order to<br />

fulfill its objectives.<br />

166. See Restrictive Trade Practices <strong>Law</strong>, supra note 83, art. 23.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 874 2006-2007


Disclosure as a Public Policy Instrument in<br />

Global Capital Markets'<br />

JANIS SARRA*<br />

ABSTRACT<br />

Globally, most jurisdictions use a disclosure-based system instead of a merit-based<br />

system in their securities law regimes. Disclosure enhances capital market efficiency<br />

through effective dissemination of information that is material to investor decisions, in<br />

turn facilitating the raising of capital in a cost-effective and timely manner. This article<br />

examines selective aspects of disclosure in securities law across numerous jurisdictions,<br />

specifically, how it serves as a public policy instrument in capital markets. It explores<br />

whether the current regulatory framework encourages "full, true, and plain"<br />

disclosure, concluding that the increasing complexity of products and the rapid growth<br />

in electronic-based disclosure offers both upside potential and downside risks to<br />

market integrity. The article also considers "materiality" as the standard for disclosure,<br />

including the interplay between statutory requirements and deference to business<br />

judgment by regulators and the courts.<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. INTR O D UCTIO N ................................................................................................... 876<br />

II. DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT ............................................ 877<br />

III. FULL, TRUE, AND PLAIN D ISCLOSURE ............................................................. 854<br />

IV.<br />

ELECTRONIC DISCLOSURE AS A KEY ASPECT OF ENHANCED<br />

D ISCLO SU RE R EG IM ES ....................................................................................... 884<br />

1 This article is part of a larger project under two research grants, the first by the UBC Faculty of<br />

<strong>Law</strong>, examining securities law changes in the Pan-Pacific Region and the second, part of a research study<br />

commissioned by the Task Force to Modernize Securities Legislation in Canada as a background study for<br />

its report, CANADA STEPS UP, http://www.tfmsl.ca. See JANIS SARRA, TASK FORCE TO MODERNIZE SEC.<br />

LEGISLATION IN CANADA, CANADA STEPS UP: MODERNIZING DISCLOSURE IN CANADIAN SECURITIES<br />

LAW: AN ASSESSMENT OF RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN CANADA AND SELECTED JURISDICTIONS (2006),<br />

http://www.tfmsl.ca/docs/V2(lA)%2OSarra.pdf.<br />

Associate Dean and Associate Professor, University of British Columbia Faculty of <strong>Law</strong> and<br />

Director of the National Centre for Business <strong>Law</strong>.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 875 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:875<br />

V . M A TER IA LITY ...................................................................................................... 888<br />

VI.<br />

INTERPLAY BETWEEN BUSINESS JUDGMENT AND DISCLOSURE<br />

O B LIG A TIO N S ...................................................................................................... 893<br />

VII.<br />

DEVELOPMENT AN ELECTRONIC INTEGRATED MARKET DISCLOSURE<br />

D O CU M E N T .......................................................................................................... 895<br />

V III. C O N CLU SIO N ....................................................................................................... 897<br />

I. INTRODUCTION<br />

Disclosure is a critically important public policy instrument in securities law.<br />

Globally, most, if not all, jurisdictions use a disclosure-based system instead of a<br />

merit-based system. A disclosure-based system allows securities to be issued and<br />

traded where regulators and stock exchanges are satisfied that an issuer meets<br />

disclosure requirements. Disclosure is aimed at providing timely, accurate, and<br />

complete information to the market, so that investors can make informed choices<br />

based on relevant information about the issuer's activities. It places responsibility<br />

for accurate disclosure in the hands of those with the information, who are seeking a<br />

wide market in which to raise capital. Disclosure enhances capital market efficiency<br />

because it can ensure effective dissemination of information that is material to<br />

investor decisions, in turn facilitating the raising of capital in a cost-effective and<br />

timely manner. In such a system, judgments about the "merits" of a particular<br />

product or issuer are left to the purchaser.<br />

Information about an issuer is a valuable good that drives market moves, with<br />

securities trading based largely on a standard of fair access to information. 2<br />

However, equal access to information is not a guarantee that information is a<br />

ubiquitous good that necessarily leads to fairness in the market, as retail investors<br />

have different time, resources, and capacities to digest and make use of the<br />

information.' Yet as a normative starting point, access to information that is full,<br />

true, plain, and timely does create the potential for equal use of that information by<br />

market participants. Since the premise of securities law is that the market will<br />

reward issuers engaged in effective governance, appropriate risk taking, and wealth<br />

maximizing activities through the value of shares in the market, consequent credit<br />

ratings and other measures, information creates the conditions for those activities to<br />

be rewarded.'<br />

Implicit in the linking of disclosure with investor protection is the assumption<br />

that investors with fair access to information will make rational choices, rational in<br />

this context meaning the capacity to use the disclosed information to act in their own<br />

best interests in market transactions.' However, behavioral economics has<br />

2. SARRA, supra note 1, at 19.<br />

3. Id.<br />

4. Id.<br />

5. Id. at 20.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 876 2006-2007


2007<br />

DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT<br />

questioned whether disclosure in itself is sufficient to overcome particular human<br />

decision-making tendencies that inhibit the ability to be rational in market<br />

transactions.' Hence, it is unlikely that there is a model that perfectly protects<br />

investors. Moreover, investors draw different conclusions about the same data,<br />

which is why there are both buyers and sellers of a stock on a given day. The real<br />

issue in respect of disclosure is whether the information is of sufficient quality and<br />

quantity to allow investors to make informed investment decisions or assess<br />

investment advice.<br />

This article examines selective aspects of disclosure in securities law,<br />

specifically, how it serves as a public policy instrument in capital markets. It<br />

explores whether the current regulatory framework encourages "full, true, and<br />

plain" disclosure, concluding that while the full and true aspects have received<br />

considerable attention in recent years, the increasing complexity of products creates<br />

challenges for achieving plain and accessible disclosure. This article also examines<br />

the potential and limits of electronic-based disclosure, suggesting that the market is<br />

ahead of the regulatory system in terms of how disclosure is made and that new<br />

measures may be required to protect the integrity of web-based disclosures. It also<br />

considers "materiality" as the standard for disclosure, including the interplay<br />

between statutory requirements and deference to business judgment in determining<br />

what information is considered material information such that it must be disclosed!<br />

Finally, as a mechanism to deal with some of the issues raised in the article, the final<br />

part proposes a new integrated market disclosure document as a means to enhance<br />

disclosure as a public policy instrument and create greater uniformity and<br />

accessibility to disclosure across multiple jurisdictions.<br />

II.<br />

DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT<br />

Disclosure is a key policy instrument in three respects: it serves as a transaction<br />

cost control device, a regulatory tool, and a governance-signaling device. 8<br />

As a policy instrument to control transaction costs, disclosure can serve to<br />

reduce the cost of access to capital and thus enhance efficiency in capital markets. 9<br />

Standardized and uniform disclosure requirements reduce transaction costs for<br />

issuers bringing securities to the market by reducing the costs of contracting for<br />

securities, including the cost of contracting contingency claims. These costs include<br />

third party costs incurred in the raising of capital, such as fees and the pricing of new<br />

capital in the market. Transaction costs, however, can vary given the frequency of<br />

rule changes, the amount of codification, and whether a rule change enhances<br />

confidence in the market. A particular level of codification can increase certainty<br />

and reduce costs; however, over-codification or rapidly changing standards can<br />

increase transaction costs as issuers try to understand and meet new requirements or<br />

6. Id. For a discussion of this issue, see JOHN R. NOFSINGER, THE PSYCHOLOGY OF INVESTING 8-17<br />

(2005); MARY G. CONDON, ANITA ANAND & JANIS SARRA, SECURITIES LAW IN CANADA: CASES AND<br />

COMMENTARY (Emond Montgomery ed., 2005).<br />

7. While another important question for exploration is whether the disclosure paradigm should be the<br />

framework used to protect investors, that question is beyond the scope of this article.<br />

8. For a full discussion, see SARRA, supra note 1, at 21.<br />

9. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 877 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:875<br />

market participants seek premiums for investment.'" Increased codification could<br />

result in an attendant increase in costs of disclosure compliance, which in turn means<br />

a higher cost of capital. Alternatively, a high level of codification could avoid<br />

making disclosure more costly but could create a "tick the box" compliance culture if<br />

it drives the system to a level of prescribed disclosure with little thought and time<br />

directed to compliance. In contrast, a well-designed, accessible system can facilitate<br />

issuer disclosure and investor decision making, resulting in more efficient trading.<br />

Second, disclosure is a policy instrument in that it serves as a measure of<br />

compliance with regulatory requirements." In Canada and the United <strong>State</strong>s, as in<br />

many jurisdictions, securities regulators assess fitness for market based on whether<br />

the issuer meets disclosure requirements. Disclosure is also the regulatory<br />

instrument for sanctioning or removing market participants. In addition, it is a tool<br />

for the creation of incentives for appropriate capital market participant behavior.<br />

For example, those issuers with recognized experience in the market and a history of<br />

compliance with securities law requirements have less onerous regulatory conditions<br />

imposed on them in bringing a new offering to the market. Hence there is an<br />

incentive to comply in order to reduce costs of future offerings. In this sense,<br />

disclosure is a regulatory tool to facilitate creating a culture of both pro-active<br />

disclosure and of compliance.<br />

Finally, disclosure has a corporate governance role as a signaling device that<br />

communicates messages to capital market participants about the issuer's governance<br />

effectiveness. 2 It serves as a signaling device for investors in respect of operational<br />

efficiency, director oversight, and managerial skills. Increased disclosure of<br />

corporate governance under "comply or explain" policies of stock exchanges and<br />

securities regulators means that there is increased information about governance<br />

practices, contingency processes, insider trading decisions, executive compensation,<br />

and board independence measures. It is also a signaling device for corporate<br />

directors, as requirements to disclose corporate governance practices force corporate<br />

boards to assess and report on upside and downside risks, which facilitates the<br />

board's own process of adjusting strategic planning and oversight of corporate<br />

officers accordingly. 13<br />

The quality of disclosure can influence market behavior, as the willingness of<br />

investors to expend their capital on a particular economic activity is affected by<br />

whether investors have confidence in the disclosures being made. Failure to achieve<br />

effective disclosure can reduce market efficiency because the cost of capital is higher<br />

and public confidence and willingness to invest are diminished.<br />

In Canada, there have been two normative directions in disclosure policy for<br />

capital markets. On the one hand is the clear move by most regulators towards<br />

increased codification through national instruments, policies, and local rules, aimed<br />

at certainty in quality of information. 4 In this respect, Canada has followed its<br />

10. Id.<br />

11. Id.<br />

12. SARRA, supra note 1, at 22.<br />

13. Id.<br />

14. See, e.g., Continuous Disclosure Obligations, National Instrument 51-102 (April 2, 2004),<br />

Acceptable Accounting Principles, Auditing Standards and Reporting Currency, National Instrument 52-<br />

107 (Jan. 16, 2004), Certification of Disclosure in Issuers' Annual and Interim Filings, Multilateral<br />

Instrument 52-109 (Jan. 16, 2004), Audit Committees, Multilateral Instrument 52-110 (Mar. 26, 2000),<br />

available at http://www.osc.gov.on.ca/Regulation/Rulemaking/Current/rrn-part5-index.jsp.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 878 2006-2007


2007<br />

DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT<br />

largest trading partner, the United <strong>State</strong>s, in large measure because of the highly<br />

integrated nature of the two countries' capital markets. One concern is whether<br />

current codification initiatives are an overreach of regulation of primary offerings. It<br />

is estimated that currently twenty-five percent of all securities regulation in Canada<br />

is aimed at the primary market, yet this market accounts for only about six percent<br />

of all trading.' 5<br />

The other normative direction is a Continuous Market Access (CMA) model,<br />

proposed by the British Columbia Securities Commission (BCSC), which is premised<br />

on the notion that principles/standards-based regulation, rather than detailed<br />

codification, will better promote the goals of investor protection, efficient markets,<br />

and public confidence in capital markets. The BCSC model aligns itself with<br />

initiatives in the United Kingdom, which the United Kingdom's Financial Services<br />

Agency (FSA) calls a hybrid of high-level principles and detailed rules and guidance<br />

that focus on best practices more than rules, with the aim of continuing to change the<br />

6<br />

balance "towards a more principles-based and less rules-based approach.'<br />

To date, these divergent approaches have created a barrier to implementing a<br />

single national securities law regime in Canada, to replace the existing thirteen<br />

provincial and territorial securities law systems. 7 Both normative views have<br />

benefits and limitations. There is a risk to accessibility for both issuers and investors<br />

in terms of understanding the nature of highly-codified obligations. At the same<br />

time, if Canadian regulatory requirements do not align to a certain extent with<br />

highly codified U.S. disclosure requirements, there could be difficulties with<br />

continued access to U.S. markets. There is also a risk of issuers missing market<br />

windows, given time delays in bringing an offering to the market where approval of<br />

multiple regulators is required. The BCSC conducted a cost-benefit analysis that<br />

suggested that the CMA model provides more expeditious and less expensive access<br />

to capital without sacrificing investor protection, and that completion of an IPO<br />

under CMA would be up to nineteen percent faster and up to fifty one percent<br />

cheaper.' Offerings after initial IPO could be up to fifty six percent faster and<br />

eighty two percent cheaper, depending on size of the issuer.' 9 Issuers would get to<br />

market faster, reducing the risk of missing market windows." The CMA is aimed at<br />

15. Proposal for a Statutory Civil Remedy for Investors in the Secondary Market and Response to the<br />

Proposed Change to the Definitions of "Material Fact" and "Material Change," Canadian Securities<br />

Administrators Notice 53-302 (Nov. 3, 2000), 23 OSCB 7383.<br />

16. FINANCIAL SERVICES AUTHORITY, BETTER REGULATION ACTION PLAN: WHAT WE HAVE<br />

DONE AND WHAT WE ARE DOING (2005), http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/other/better-regulation.pdf. The<br />

FSA writes that it is "committ[ed] to implementing directives in a sensible and proportionate way. [The<br />

FSA] must implement the minimum requirements, even if they would fail a cost-benefit analysis from the<br />

viewpoint of the UK. [The FSA] will not gold-plate EU requirements [and].. .will only add requirements<br />

when these are justified in their own right."<br />

17. There have been a considerable number of studies, wise persons committees, and reports on<br />

whether Canada should have a national regulatory system or a passport system that recognizes different<br />

jurisdictions. For a discussion of these issues, see CONDON, ANAND & SARRA, supra note 6; and CANADA<br />

STEPS UP, supra note 1.<br />

18. CHRISTINA WOLF, BETTER DISCLOSURE, LOWER COSTS: A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS OF THE<br />

CONTINUOUS MARKET ACCESS SYSTEM 7. 11 (Deregulation Project 2002),<br />

http://www.bcsc.bc.ca/uploadedFiles/CBA-Report.pdf.<br />

19. /dat8,11.<br />

20. Id. The study suggested that prospectus costs for issuers listed on the Toronto Stock Exchange<br />

(TSX) are directly related to length, each page of additional prospectus disclosure costs an issuer about<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 879 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:875<br />

benefiting investors by improving disclosure and benefiting issuers by significantly<br />

lowering their capital-raising costs.<br />

While there is not yet convergence of these normative approaches, there has<br />

been some loosening of the views regarding principles-based versus rules-based<br />

approaches to disclosure regulation. For example, in the United <strong>State</strong>s, the SEC has<br />

recently recognized the need for at least a partially principles-based approach. To<br />

date, regulatory change in the United <strong>State</strong>s has been highly rules driven,<br />

particularly in the years after Enron and other corporate failures. Yet the SEC has<br />

adopted a partially principles-based approach to its new requirements on executive<br />

compensation disclosure, effective December 2006. The new Compensation<br />

Discussion and Analysis (CD&A) document aims to provide clear and complete<br />

disclosure of senior officers' compensation, using both the SEC requirements that it<br />

be in plain language and principles-based requirements to explain all material<br />

elements of compensation. 2 '<br />

III. FULL, TRUE, AND PLAIN DISCLOSURE<br />

A critical challenge in thinking about disclosure as a public policy instrument is how<br />

truly to make information accessible while also ensuring that issuers disclose the<br />

level of detail and depth necessary for analysts to make informed decisions. This<br />

question implicates three principal parties to the disclosure: the issuer, the investor,<br />

and the market intermediaries. 22 For the issuer, disclosure requirements must be<br />

sufficiently clear so that the issuer can, with some certainty, meet the requirements<br />

without unreasonable transaction costs. For the investor, disclosure must allow for<br />

informed decisions. Because retail investors are increasingly involved in the market<br />

both through on-line facilities and managed investment funds, the nature of investor<br />

interest lies more along a continuum of interests, information, and sophistication,<br />

rather than a two-tier dichotomy between retail and institutional investors.<br />

Institutional investors also run along that continuum: while they are sophisticated<br />

investors, institutional investors have different interests, time horizons, and priorities<br />

in their market activity, and thus may have different disclosure needs. 23 For<br />

example, institutional investors interested in long-term investments view governance<br />

disclosure as important. For investment analysts, retail stock brokers, fund<br />

managers, and other intermediaries, there are obligations to responsibly digest,<br />

filter, and provide opinions on disclosure. Parts of the market are highly dependent<br />

on the ability of these intermediaries to decipher complex disclosures and deliver<br />

skilled advice to the market.<br />

Disclosure documents should clearly identify their purpose and provide "full,<br />

true, and plain" information in an accessible form. "Full" disclosure requires a level<br />

of completeness in material information such that investors can make informed<br />

decisions. "True" denotes a level of correctness and honesty. "Plain" includes clear,<br />

simple, and readily understood. While plain language may be necessary for<br />

unsophisticated retail investors or those investors without the resources to analyze<br />

$29,000.<br />

21. SEC News Release 2006-123, SEC Votes to Adopt Changes to Disclosure Requirements<br />

Concerning Executive Compensation and Related Matters (July 26, 2006).<br />

http://www.sec.gov/news/press/2006/2006-123.htm.<br />

22. SARRA, supra note 1, at 36.<br />

23. Id. at 37.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 880 2006-2007


2007<br />

DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT<br />

all disclosure documents, disclosure requirements must nevertheless continue to<br />

provide analysts, institutional investors, and other market participants with the level<br />

of detail necessary to make informed judgments about investment advice and to<br />

provide regulators with the level of transparency necessary for regulatory approval<br />

or monitoring.<br />

Although many regulatory systems have focused on the "full and true" aspects<br />

of disclosure, only more recently has the "plain" aspect of disclosure received<br />

attention. This is partially because of the size, complexity, and variety of securities<br />

offerings, as well as the increased codification of requirements. In part, it is because<br />

electronic filing or required disclosure of particular information has been added<br />

incrementally to the system without sufficient consideration of the overall<br />

implications for full, true, and plain disclosure. This creates new problems of<br />

access." The FSA in the United Kingdom and the SEC in the United <strong>State</strong>s have<br />

both recently stated that plain language will be a priority for their future regulatory<br />

requirements in respect of disclosure." 5<br />

Internationally, there are numerous plain language initiatives aimed at<br />

providing meaningful full, true, and plain disclosure. The International Organization<br />

of Securities Commissions (IOSCO) has had a series of initiatives towards plain<br />

language disclosure, which are referred to by regulators of numerous jurisdictions to<br />

inform their initiatives. For example, the European Union's Prospectus Directive<br />

requires that information disclosed in prospectus documents be presented in an<br />

easily understandable and comprehensible form. 26 The summary to the prospectus is<br />

limited to 2,500 words that convey in a brief manner and in non-technical language<br />

the "essential characteristics and risks associated with the issuer, any guarantor and<br />

the securities." 27 While the required plain language summary statement is an<br />

important initiative, the European Union has determined that the summary must<br />

contain a warning that it should be read as an introduction to the prospectus, and a<br />

summary sheet to a prospectus will not attract liability unless it is misleading,<br />

inaccurate, or inconsistent when read together with other parts of the prospectus. 2 "<br />

That raises the question of whether the liability line has been drawn in the<br />

appropriate place for such summaries. The EU Prospectus Directive does impose<br />

certainty across the European Economic Area (EEA) in that regulators cannot opt<br />

out of the liability protections afforded to issuers completing the summary, which<br />

fosters the efficient market goal of securities regulation.<br />

24. Id. at 39.<br />

25. Financial Services Authority, Getting Investment Disclosure Right (2006),,<br />

http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/other/disclosure-factsheet.pdf; Christopher Cox, Chairman, U.S. Sec. and<br />

Exch. Comm'n., Videotaped Remarks to the San Jose, CA XBRL Conference (Jan. 18, 2006) (transcript<br />

available at http://www.sec.gov/news/speech/spch011806cc.htm).<br />

26. Directive 2003/71/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 4 November 2003 on the<br />

Prospectus to be Published when Securities are Offered to the Public or Admitted to Trading and Amending<br />

Directive 2001/34/EC, 2003 O.J. (L 345) art. 5(1)[hereinafter EU Prospectus Directive]; Commission<br />

Regulation (EC) No. 809/2004, 2004 O.J. (L 149) para. 30. The EU Prospectus Directive has as its purpose<br />

the harmonization of requirements for creation and distribution of prospectuses when securities are to be<br />

offered to the public or an issuer admitted to trading on a regulated market.<br />

27. EU Prospectus Directive, supra note 26, pmbl. § 21, art. 5(2).<br />

28. Id. art. 5(2). There is no requirement to provide a summary where the securities relate to nonequity<br />

securities having a denomination of EUR 50.000, except when requested by a member state.<br />

29. Once a prospectus is approved in one EEA country, it can be used to issue in any other EEA<br />

country. In the EU, a significant recent development for primary market disclosure is the move in 2005<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 881 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:875<br />

Many jurisdictions lack integration between primary and secondary market<br />

disclosure requirements. Consequently, information overlap, duplication, and<br />

fragmentation create issues of clarity and accessibility. In Canada, for example,<br />

primary market disclosure is contained in the prospectus and the Annual<br />

Information Form (AIF). For specialized offerings, such as the prompt offering<br />

prospectus, the information is disclosed in the prospectus, the AIF, the financial<br />

statements, and any material change reports." In secondary market disclosure,<br />

information is disclosed in financial statements, AIFs, Management Discussion and<br />

Analysis (MD&A), proxy circulars, and material change reports. The different<br />

statutory disclosure requirements between primary and secondary market disclosure<br />

means that information is often inaccessible to retail investors because it is located in<br />

different places during different periods of the issuer's distribution and continuous<br />

disclosure life cycles. The upsurge in the quantity of information in recent years<br />

often means that the information is publicly disclosed through multiple sources, and<br />

it is difficult for investors, particularly some retail investors, to acquire a full and<br />

accurate picture of the issuer's activities and business risks. It can also be difficult to<br />

assess how material or significant the disclosure is. Although the periodic disclosure<br />

documents such as financial statements, AIFs, and MD&As are required to give a<br />

full picture, in the interim periods, material change and other reporting can be<br />

located in a myriad of places, and can give mixed messages to investors about the<br />

risk and return decisions faced by an issuer."<br />

There are signs of a move toward more integrated disclosure in Canada. In<br />

2006, the change to short form prospectus requirements illustrated the move toward<br />

recognizing a continuous disclosure record, whether for the primary or secondary<br />

market. Short form prospectuses were historically only available to issuers with<br />

considerable market experience or sizable capitalization, which allowed those issuers<br />

to bring an offering to market quickly and with less cost. The new national<br />

instrument regulating short form prospectus offerings has eliminated many<br />

seasoning and minimum market capitalization requirements, thus expanding<br />

eligibility criteria for accessing short form offerings to include most Canadian listed<br />

issuers. 32 These changes facilitate access to capital markets by permitting issuers to<br />

rely increasingly on their continuous disclosure record. Broader qualification<br />

requirements enable more issuers to take advantage of the short form prospectus<br />

system. With 3,800 issuers listed on the TSX and TSX Venture Exchange, 33 the new<br />

requirements will allow several thousand more issuers to use short form<br />

prospectuses, and thus give many small and mid-cap issuers access to a national<br />

market on a more expeditious and cost-effective basis.<br />

from a recognition system to a full passport system for prospectus offerings throughout the European<br />

Economic Area (EEA), which is comprised of all EU member states plus Norway, Iceland and<br />

Liechtenstein. Id. art. 1(1).<br />

30. CONDON, ANAND, & SARRA, supra note 6.<br />

31. SARRA, supra note 1, at 47.<br />

32. SHORT FORM PROSPECrUS DISTRIBUTIONS, NATIONAL INSTRUMENT 44-101, ONTARIO SEC.<br />

COMM'N, available at http://www.osc.gov.on.ca/Regulation/Rulemaking/Current/Part4/rule_20061222_41-<br />

101gen-pro-requirements.pdf; CONTINUOUS DISCLOSURE OBLIGATIONS, NATIONAL INSTRUMENT 51-<br />

102, ONTARIO SEC. COMM'N., available at<br />

http://www.osc.gov.on.ca/Regulation/Rulemaking/Current/Part5/rule_20031219_51-102_con-dis.pdf.<br />

33. WISE PERSONS' COMMITTEE TO REVIEW THE STRUCTURE OF SECURITIES REGULATION IN<br />

CANADA, IT'S TIME 5 (Ottawa Dept. of Finance, 2003), http://www.wiseaverties.ca/reports/WPC%20Final.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 882 2006-2007


2007<br />

DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT<br />

In the United <strong>State</strong>s, recent changes are aimed at enhancing timely delivery of<br />

information to investors while controlling costs to market. The Securities Offering<br />

Reform Rules, effective December 2005, created a new class of "well-known<br />

seasoned issuers" (WKSIs) comprised of issuers that are widely followed in the<br />

marketplace." WKSIs can use a new "automatic shelf registration" process, which<br />

allows them to register unspecified amounts of specified types or classes of securities<br />

on immediately effective registration statements, without allocating between primary<br />

and secondary offerings, and can exclude more information from the base<br />

prospectus. WKSIs eliminate the delivery requirement for final prospectuses,<br />

liberalizing issuer communications so that more information goes to the market<br />

earlier in the process. 3 5 The shelf registration rules for WKSIs allow more flexibility<br />

and faster issuing. As in Canada, the United <strong>State</strong>s is now distinguishing between<br />

those issuers well known to the market and those that are new, in terms of the extent<br />

of additional disclosures required to bring a new issue to the market. While these<br />

developments in Canada and the United <strong>State</strong>s are important for time to market,<br />

they do not address potential fragmentation of information and the question of<br />

access to full, true and plain disclosure.<br />

Investor education is another aspect of the disclosure system because it can<br />

enhance investor knowledge and provide skills to assess disclosures. While<br />

education does not remedy an individual's capacity to digest and apply information,<br />

it can serve to reduce disparities in processing information and reduce the incidence<br />

of completely uninformed decision making. Education can provide investors with a<br />

greater appreciation of their own limits (time, resources and information) with<br />

respect to investment decisions without the assistance of knowledgeable advisors.<br />

Realistically, the vast majority of investors do not make investments themselves;<br />

instead, they retain retail stock brokers, mutual fund managers, or others to provide<br />

them with advice or to direct their investment portfolio. Although technically<br />

individual retail investors make the actual decision to buy, sell, or hold, in reality the<br />

analyst is often the de facto investment decision-maker. In the United Kingdom,<br />

there has been a requirement since June 2005 that analysts give investors two<br />

'keyfacts' documents at the start of the advice process, in order to provide retail<br />

investors "...with clear and understandable information about the products and<br />

services offer[ed], and the cost of advice...", as well as information about "...all<br />

options that are available in the market, not just what [the firm] offers." 36 These<br />

requirements acknowledge the limitations of disclosure in terms of how retail<br />

investors may rely on the advice of intermediaries in the marketplace, and places<br />

some obligation on advisors to disclose the scope and limits of their own services<br />

within the market for disclosure and investment advice.<br />

In summary, the objective of full, true, and plain disclosure is hindered by<br />

fragmentation of information, the complexity of products now offered in the market,<br />

a lack of integration between primary and secondary market disclosure<br />

34. Securities Offering Reform, SEC Release No. 33-8591 (19 July 2005) 70 FR 44722; Rules 415, 424,<br />

430B, Registration Procedures for United <strong>State</strong>s public offerings.<br />

35. Id. Rule 163.<br />

36. Getting Investment Disclosure Right, supra note 25. These documents are: Keyfacts About Our<br />

Services - also known as the initial disclosure document or IDD: and Keyfacts About The Cost Of Our<br />

Services - also known as the menu (or fees and commission statement) or a combined initial disclosure<br />

(CIDD) document instead of an IDD.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 883 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:875<br />

requirements, the incremental and often unplanned nature of new disclosure<br />

requirements added to pre-existing rules, and the filtering that occurs as information<br />

changes hands before the investment decision is made.<br />

IV. ELECTRONIC DISCLOSURE AS A KEY ASPECT OF ENHANCED<br />

DISCLOSURE REGIMES<br />

Methods of disclosure communication have radically changed. Whereas<br />

historically, the paper prospectus was the principal protection device, paper<br />

generally has been replaced by electronic and web-based communication. The<br />

exponential increase in the use of web-based platforms and other technology has<br />

quite literally revolutionized access to information. In Canada, for example,<br />

investors can access information about issuers through the System for Electronic<br />

Document Analysis and Retrieval (SEDAR), the System for Electronic Disclosure<br />

by Insiders (SEDI), stock exchange listings, company web-sites, electronically posted<br />

information about legal actions that the issuer is involved in, and a host of other<br />

portals through which information is now disseminated. 37<br />

However, the material information contained in these systems is not always<br />

easily accessible. Disclosures are posted in multiple places on the website and it<br />

takes a certain amount of time, talent, and tenacity to find all material information. 38<br />

Some investors may believe that they are making decisions based on full and<br />

complete information, but they may have missed an important material change<br />

report buried within the site. Liberal access to web-based information has thus<br />

created a new tension in the disclosure debate. On one side of this debate, electronic<br />

and web-based disclosures are enhancing the ability of issuers to make full, timely,<br />

and material disclosure to a broader range of market participants. This protects<br />

investors because both primary and secondary market disclosures are more<br />

accessible. Timely disclosure increases market efficiency because it allows the<br />

market to respond to earnings statements or material changes rapidly, and alerts all<br />

market participants to developments that may influence their investment decisions.<br />

While in some countries there may be concern regarding access to web-based<br />

disclosure, this concern is less likely to be a justification for maintaining the current<br />

paper-based system because those engaged in securities markets are increasingly<br />

likely to have access to web-based information.<br />

On the other side of the debate, there is a risk that accessible but extensive<br />

information will reduce true access to information for investors, particularly with the<br />

use of hyper-links and different web-platforms that can obscure access to<br />

information for investors. Hyper-links can perform an important disclosure role in<br />

directing the investor to the appropriate place in the disclosure documents, where an<br />

issue is more fully discussed. The more sophisticated and exciting the delivery, for<br />

example, shifting back and forth from formal disclosure documents to video-footage<br />

of recent resource discoveries, however, the greater the risk of missing important<br />

information. Hyper-links can also take the investor to related web-sites where other<br />

parties are responsible for the disclosure content. In such cases, it is not always clear<br />

37. System for Electronic Document Analysis and Retrieval (SEDAR), National Instrument 13-101,<br />

Ontario Sec. Comm'n, http://ftp.sfsc.gov.sk.ca/scripts/ssc/files/nat-inst/13-101niamendedasof-mar3O-04.pdf;<br />

Canadian Securities Administrators SEDI Home Page, http://www.csa-acvm.ca/htmlCSA/sedi.html.<br />

38. SARRA, supra note 1, at 44.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 884 2006-2007


2007<br />

DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT<br />

that the investor is leaving a web-site for which the issuer assumes responsibility and<br />

exiting to another site not within the issuer's control in terms of accuracy and<br />

completeness of information. The issue of transparency needs to be addressed in<br />

thinking about the move to a primarily web-based disclosure regime. The choice of<br />

where to locate all disclosure information is a critical one that may affect the market.<br />

If a "one-click full access" system was the responsibility of individual issuers, the<br />

costs could become quite onerous in terms of IT support. Yet more than 90% of<br />

Toronto Stock Exchange (TSX) listed companies already maintain web-based<br />

disclosure, suggesting that the market has determined this is a timely way to ensure<br />

disclosure to the market.<br />

Web-based communication also allows investment dealers and other<br />

intermediaries to access information and to digest, analyze, and disseminate that<br />

information to their client base in a timely manner. Historically, the market was<br />

structured so that these participants were able to access disclosures more readily<br />

than retail investors and hence differential access created a market demand for their<br />

services. Increased direct access may diminish that traditional market. At the same<br />

time, there is a growing demand for investment advice as the range and diversity of<br />

products increases. Hence, better discipline in respect of web-based disclosure<br />

should enhance market choices overall. Electronic disclosure may also create<br />

greater incentives for analysts and other market participants to maintain or enhance<br />

the quality of their advice, as retail investors will have the option of accessing the<br />

market directly. 9<br />

A number of web-based, electronic, or technology-based initiatives have<br />

enhanced access to disclosure in recent years. Electronic road shows are increasingly<br />

available, allowing investors from remote locations to access information meetings<br />

and ask questions about securities being brought to the market. In China, such<br />

electronic road shows are now mandatory with any new offering. Another example<br />

is the growing practice of advance notice of earnings announcements, with the<br />

electronic capacity to be on-line for the announcement or to hear the announcement<br />

on a deferred basis but first-hand. Electronic disclosure is now part of the market,<br />

and regulators should use these advances to promote enhanced quality and<br />

timeliness of issuer disclosure. Creating access to analyst calls, where the issuer<br />

discusses particular issues with analysts, is also a positive development in disclosure<br />

access. While most retail investors do not have the time or resources to follow<br />

analyst calls, the participation of intermediaries and those investors able to<br />

participate is likely to help ensure that inappropriate or unfairly advantageous<br />

disclosure does not occur.<br />

Many jurisdictions are moving to an "access equals delivery" system such as the<br />

delivery of WKSI disclosure in the United <strong>State</strong>s. Notwithstanding that there may<br />

be a lingering concern that some investors do not have consistent access to webbased<br />

disclosure, the system could shift to a default-based system where investors<br />

receive notice that documents have been posted with the appropriate web-links and<br />

an option to receive paper-based disclosure. Web-based communications platforms<br />

can allow for the reduction of information asymmetries and can enhance timely,<br />

extensive disclosure that is accessible to everyone seeking to participate in the<br />

market.<br />

39. Id. at 46.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 885 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:875<br />

If web-based disclosure access is to equal delivery of information for purposes<br />

of meeting market disclosure requirements, it is important to build in a high degree<br />

of investor protection, including measures that guard against information tampering.<br />

It is also important that regulators are able to monitor disclosure, given its function<br />

as a regulatory tool. The design of a system that allows certainty in tracking,<br />

especially disclosure as ephemeral as electronic information, will require some care.<br />

Attention will also have to be paid to how securities holders can establish delivery or<br />

non-delivery of information where they seek remedies for breach of disclosure<br />

requirements. While statutory deemed reliance provisions will alleviate some of this<br />

concern, it may become a practical challenge in establishing the timing of issuer<br />

disclosure on a particular matter. 0 Requiring all continuous disclosure to be housed<br />

in one location, perhaps the issuer's web-page, would, address the fragmentation<br />

problems discussed earlier.<br />

One question is whether there should be a market for centralizing data for<br />

investors. While this might provide an accessible service for investors, there is also<br />

the public policy issue of preservation, storage, and retrieval of that data in case of<br />

compliance or civil liability issues. Even without the use of centralized data services,<br />

investors may face difficulty in pursuing civil liability claims based on electronic<br />

documents that they did not download at the point in time for which they later seek<br />

to impugn the disclosure conduct. Without paper-based copies, the system design<br />

will need to ensure timely and cost-effective access to that point-in-time disclosure or<br />

there will be enormous transaction costs associated with litigating access to<br />

"disclosure of the point-in-time disclosure."<br />

Similarly, while some technology would allow for particular investors to<br />

customize document disclosure, one needs to be concerned about disclosure that, in<br />

customizing data for investors, alters the first-hand disclosure by issuers. The<br />

second-hand reporting may diminish the ability of investors to hold issuers<br />

accountable for disclosure information on which they based their investment<br />

decisions. While issuers in such circumstances should be protected, there may need<br />

to be a liability regime that holds the service customizing data responsible for the<br />

integrity of the disclosures. Adoption of new technological strategies must take<br />

account of these concerns. The issue is what use of technology will enhance<br />

disclosure and promote the objectives of securities legislation. The responsive<br />

capacity exists; it needs to be implemented in a manner that allows issuers costeffective<br />

disclosure delivery while protecting investors of all kinds along the<br />

continuum of sophistication and interest.<br />

Another issue is whether there should be a private market for electronic<br />

disclosure that operates above the publicly regulated structure. For example, in<br />

Canada, CDS INC., which operates SEDAR on behalf of the Canadian securities<br />

regulatory authorities, offers a new service on its own web-site called SEDAR-<br />

SCRIBE, a service that gives subscribers immediate disclosure of SEDAR filings 12-<br />

24 hours before they are posted for the general public." Arguably, this could create<br />

a two-tiered electronic disclosure system with more timely disclosure for those<br />

market participants that can afford to pay. If disclosure is a good that we want to be<br />

40. Technological developments can reduce the cost of delivery for issuers. However, it is unlikely to<br />

be an overall cost savings, as moving to a fully integrated web-based or electronic disclosure system<br />

requires full-time ongoing IT and IP support to ensure that continuous disclosure is accurate and timely.<br />

41. SEDAR-SCRIBE: CDS Innovations Inc. Filing Information Home Page,<br />

http://www.cdsinnovations.ca/cdsinnovationshome.nsf[Pages/-EN-Filinginformation?Open.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 886 2006-2007


2007<br />

DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT<br />

uniformly accessible as a public policy matter, then the appropriateness of such<br />

services may have to be examined. 42<br />

In the European Union, issuers are to ensure that where a prospectus is<br />

published in electronic form, safety measures are to be used to maintain the integrity<br />

of the information, and to avoid manipulation or modification from unauthorized<br />

persons. "3 The prospectus must be easily accessible when entering the web-site: it<br />

must not contain hyper-links, with the exception of links to the electronic addresses<br />

where information incorporated by reference is available, and the investor must be<br />

able to download and print the prospectus.' The prohibition on most hyper-links is<br />

an interesting regulatory choice, particularly when other jurisdictions are exploring<br />

allowing the use of hyper-links to amplify disclosure information. While the EU has<br />

made a fulsome shift towards electronic disclosure, it still provides investors with a<br />

basic right to return to paper-based delivery free of charge. 4<br />

In the United <strong>State</strong>s, the SEC is promoting a new electronic platform called<br />

eXtensible Business Reporting Language (XBRL), developed by an international<br />

consortium of 400 major companies and government agencies. About 30 U.S. filers<br />

with US$1 trillion in capital are currently using XBRL on a pilot basis. 46 XBRL is<br />

also being tested in Europe, Canada and other jurisdictions. XBRL attaches<br />

standardized electronic tags to elements of information on financial statements. The<br />

tagged data can then be pulled out of the comprehensive electronic disclosures,<br />

allowing investors to draw out the information they are interested in examining on a<br />

selective basis. It also allows software programs to calculate ratios and perform<br />

other analyses without having to re-input financial data, providing enhanced access<br />

to information for analysts and other financial intermediaries. The express objective<br />

of XBRL is to "level the playing field for tens of millions of average investors." 47<br />

The drive behind the initiative is the SEC's conclusion that the solution to<br />

accessible disclosure for retail investors is not to eliminate detailed information and<br />

replace it with summaries, but rather to allow each investor to order up his or her<br />

own custom information instantly to one page, removing the necessity of culling<br />

through data where originally entered. If the platform is as accessible as the SEC<br />

believes, this could revolutionize electronic disclosure. In September 2006, the SEC<br />

announced that it will expend $54 million to makes its disclosure system, EDGAR,<br />

interactive using the XBRL computer language. 8 Currently, the EDGAR public<br />

disclosure system houses 700,000 new disclosure documents per year, and the project<br />

is aimed at allowing investors and advisors to search information more efficiently<br />

and effectively. 49<br />

42. For a discussion of this issue, see SARRA, supra note 1, at 47.<br />

43. EU Prospectus Directive, supra note 26.<br />

44. Id. art. 14(7).<br />

45. Id. para. 31, art. 14(7).<br />

46. Christopher Cox, Videotaped Remarks to the San Jose, CA XBRL Conference, supra note 24.<br />

47. Christopher Cox, Chairman, U.S. Sec. and Exch. Comm'n., Opening Remarks to the Practicing<br />

<strong>Law</strong> Institute's SEC Speaks Series (Mar. 3, 2006) (transcript available at<br />

http://www.sec.gov/news/speech/spch030306cc.htm).<br />

48. SEC News Release 2006-158, SEC to Rebuild Public Disclosure System to Make it 'Interactive.'<br />

(Nov. 29, 2006), http://www.sec.gov/news/press/2006/2006-123.htm.<br />

49. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 887 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:875<br />

The sheer volume of disclosures makes it apparent that electronic disclosure<br />

does not necessarily guarantee full and true disclosure. The SEC has recognized this<br />

in its new initiatives. In China, regulators have moved quite aggressively into use of<br />

technology in market disclosure. Financial statements, interim announcements and<br />

other relevant documentation of companies are required to be entirely disclosed on<br />

the websites of the stock exchanges. ° While the use of internet-based disclosure has<br />

resulted in a significant expansion of the amount of disclosure, the technological<br />

advances have also amplified the risks in the market. China faces new challenges of<br />

data quality, reliability and the potential abuse of the internet to disseminate<br />

misleading information, provide false advice, defraud investors and manipulate the<br />

market. Its regulators are currently engaged in a process to improve the integrity of<br />

electronic disclosures.<br />

V. MATERIALITY<br />

Material fact, material change, and material information - these terms denote<br />

the scope and timing of information that is to be brought to the market. Not all<br />

information of an issuer should be disclosed to the market because it would create an<br />

inordinate burden on issuers if they were required to report continually their<br />

activities and financial condition, and would flood the market with excessive and<br />

transient information. Hence, regulators throughout the world have adopted the<br />

approach that it is material information that must be disclosed. Investors are to be<br />

given information that can inform their decisions to buy, sell, or hold. In some<br />

jurisdictions, "material" is defined as what a reasonable investor would consider<br />

important to his or her investment decision, referred to as the reasonable investor<br />

test. In other jurisdictions, it is information that is likely to affect the value of the<br />

securities, referred to as the market-impact test. In reality, there is overlap between<br />

these tests: what is considered material because it has the potential of affecting the<br />

value of securities will always be information that a reasonable investor would want.<br />

There are issues, however, in determining materiality, particularly as some<br />

jurisdictions make distinctions between material facts and material changes in terms<br />

of disclosure requirements. Corporate officers determine materiality, yet there can<br />

be an uncomfortable fit between statutory standards of materiality and whether<br />

deference should be given to corporate officers in their determination that particular<br />

information is not material.<br />

The EU Prospectus Directive specifies that the prospectus is to contain all<br />

information that is necessary to enable investors "to make an informed assessment<br />

of the assets and liabilities, financial position... and prospects of issuers..." based on<br />

a materiality standard." There is optional disclosure of financial forecasts, but such<br />

forecasts must be presented in a consistent and comparable manner that is not to be<br />

confused with disclosure of known trends or other factual data with material impact<br />

on the issuer's prospects." Supplements to the prospectus are required for "every<br />

significant new factor, material mistake or inaccuracy relating to the information<br />

50. China Securities Regulatory Commission, Collection of <strong>Law</strong>s and Regulations of Securities and<br />

Futures of the People's Republic of China (2002), http://www.csrc.gov.cn.<br />

51. European Union Prospectus Directive, supra note 26 art. 5(1) (stating the information is to be<br />

according to the particular nature of the issuer and of the securities offered to the public or admitted to<br />

trading on a regulated market.).<br />

52. Id. para. 8.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 888 2006-2007


2007<br />

DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT<br />

included in the prospectus that is capable of affecting the assessment of the<br />

securities," if it arises between the time the prospectus is approved and the final<br />

closing of the offer to the public. 3 No distinction is made between material fact and<br />

material change in the disclosure obligations.<br />

In Canada, a distinction continues to be made between material fact and<br />

change in securities statutes. A major contested point in Canada is whether the<br />

current distinction between material fact and material change ought to be<br />

eliminated. Material fact is defined as "a fact that would reasonably be expected to<br />

have a significant effect on the market price or value of the securities".' Material<br />

change is defined as "a change [or decision to change] in the business, operations or<br />

capital of the issuer that would reasonably be expected to have a significant effect on<br />

the market price or value of any of the securities of the issuer." 55 Once a prospectus<br />

is given a receipt by securities regulators, there is no obligation to update material<br />

facts during the offering period, whereas there is an obligation to disclose material<br />

changes. 56 Hence the delineation between material fact and material change<br />

becomes significant. The Ontario Court of Appeal in Kerr v. Danier Leather<br />

recently held that a prospectus is only required to provide full, plain and true<br />

disclosure of all material facts as of the date of the prospectus, not the date of<br />

closing. 57 This is a less rigorous standard than under the European Union's<br />

Prospectus Directive. The judgment in Kerr v. Danier Leather indicates that<br />

investors' expectations of accuracy in prospectus disclosure may be incongruent with<br />

the statutory provisions. Canadian judgments suggest that there is still not a clear or<br />

shared understanding by regulators, market participants, and the courts regarding<br />

the difference between material fact and material change. The Supreme Court of<br />

Canada has granted leave to appeal in the Kerr v. Danier Leather case and the<br />

matter is pending as this article goes to press."'<br />

Here, the law lags behind market developments. Issuers listed on the Toronto<br />

Stock Exchange (TSX) are required to disclose to a material information standard. 59<br />

For these issuers, the material fact/change distinction only becomes significant if<br />

there is a claim of failure to meet statutory requirements or a civil liability claim. At<br />

that point, the issuer may try to categorize changes as material facts if not disclosed,<br />

in order to avoid liability. This after-the-fact apportioning of materiality to<br />

"disclosure boxes" seems an inappropriate way to determine statutory compliance.<br />

For many issuers, the difficulty is whether and at what point the information is<br />

material, not whether it is a fact or a change. The relatively new National Policy 51-<br />

201 Disclosure Standards recommends a material information standard, but to date,<br />

Canadian statutes have not been amended to align. The proposed Continuous<br />

Market Access model, aimed at creating consistency in reporting material<br />

information, would eliminate the distinction between material fact and material<br />

53. Id. art. 16(1).<br />

54. Ontario Securities Act, R.S.O. 1990, ch. S5, as amended, §1(1). For the Qu6bec provisions, see<br />

Quebec Securities Act, R.S.Q. ch. V-1.1 §§ 25, 68, 73.<br />

55. Ontario Securities Act, §1(1).<br />

56. Kerr v. Danier Leather Inc., [2005] O.J. No. 5388 (Ont. C.A.), leave to appeal to the Supreme<br />

Court of Canada granted, Kerr v. Danier Leather Inc. [2006] SCCA No. 56 (Can.).<br />

57. Id.<br />

58. Id.<br />

59. Toronto Stock Exchange, Policy <strong>State</strong>ment on Timely Disclosure and Related Guidelines,<br />

http://www.tsx.com/en/pdf/Policy<strong>State</strong>mentOnTimelyDisclosureNotes.pdf.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 889 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:875<br />

change and require continuous up-to-date disclosure of all material information<br />

about issuers, whether or not issuers raise capital in a given year.<br />

To satisfy the United <strong>State</strong>s' materiality standard in disclosure obligations,<br />

there must be a substantial likelihood that a fact "would have been viewed by the<br />

reasonable investor as having significantly altered the 'total mix' of information<br />

made available." 60 This is a common law, not statutory, test of materiality. Hence in<br />

terms of material disclosure, Canada has a market impact test and the United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

and the European Union have a reasonable investor test.<br />

Other countries have attached disclosure requirements to a materiality<br />

standard. In Japan, continuous disclosure obligations include disclosure of financial<br />

and other information that will significantly affect investors' decisions, and<br />

announcements of business results and material corporate information to public<br />

investors. 6' Each issuer must designate a "Corporate Information Handling Officer"<br />

to enhance timely disclosure. 6 There is a general obligation to disclose in a manner<br />

that is "swift, accurate and fair." Issuers are also required to have a system in place<br />

capable of supporting continuous, timely, and adequate legally required periodical<br />

disclosures. 63 The Tokyo Stock Exchange (TSE) requires listed companies to<br />

disclose immediately to the public "any information that might be expected to<br />

materially affect the prices of its stocks," including financial results, capital changes,<br />

occurrence of a material fact such as a major change to shareholders, legal action or<br />

decision.6 However, one of the most serious challenges for secondary market<br />

disclosure in Japan is the lack of enforcement mechanisms, and Japan also has no<br />

mechanism for private enforcement through class-action lawsuits. 6<br />

As China moves into global capital markets, it has increasingly codified<br />

materiality disclosure requirements in an effort to remedy earlier failures to capture<br />

market confidence and to demonstrate to international investors that a rapidly<br />

emerging capital market can still provide a degree of certainty and completeness in<br />

its disclosure regime. The Collection of <strong>Law</strong>s and Regulations of Securities and<br />

Futures of the People's Republic of China, compiled by the China Securities<br />

Regulatory Commission (CSRC) in 2002, is comprised of 71 regulations and<br />

regulatory documents. 66 However, codification of materiality may not address<br />

longstanding cultural norms that do not value disclosure and hence may not comply<br />

with regulatory requirements. While this topic is beyond the scope of this discussion,<br />

it does point out that imposition of materiality standards is only one part of the<br />

equation, and there must be both a culture of compliance and enforcement<br />

mechanisms for disclosure to be effective as a public policy instrument.<br />

60. For a discussion, see CONDON, ANAND, & SARRA, supra note 6, at 269-270.<br />

61. See generally TOKYO STOCK EXCHANGE, RULES ON TIMELY DISCLOSURE OF CORPORATE<br />

INFORMATION BY ISSUER OF LISTED SECURITY AND THE LIKE (2002),<br />

http://www.tse.or.jp/english/guide/regulations/data/securitylisting.pdf.<br />

62. TOKYO STOCK EXCHANGE, SUPPLEMENTARY RULES TO SECURITY LISTING REGULATIONS, Dec.<br />

10, 2003, at Part III, Disclosure Requirements after Listing.<br />

63. Tokyo Stock Exchange Application Checklist, http://www.tse.or.jp/english at 49.<br />

64. Tokyo Stock Exchange Organization, http://www.tse.or.jp/english/about/organization.html.<br />

65. Although recently there are more accessible corporate law remedies through new provisions that<br />

facilitate derivative actions in Japan.<br />

66. Collection of <strong>Law</strong>s and Regulations of Securities and Futures of the People's Republic of China,<br />

supra note 50.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 890 2006-2007


2007<br />

DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT<br />

In the European Union, secondary market disclosure initiatives have been<br />

aimed at creating uniformity of secondary market disclosure, but have also been<br />

developed to respond to the United <strong>State</strong>s' Sarbanes-Oxley Act materiality<br />

requirements. 67 The objective of the European Commission Directive on the<br />

Harmonization of Transparency Requirements in Relation to Information about<br />

Issuers whose Securities are Admitted to Trading on a Regulated Market<br />

(Transparency Directive) is "to ensure investor confidence through equivalent<br />

transparency in disclosure throughout the [European] Community." 6 The<br />

Transparency Directive specifies that "the disclosure of accurate, comprehensive and<br />

timely information about securities issues builds sustained investor confidence and<br />

allows an informed assessment of issuers' business performance and assets." 9<br />

In the United <strong>State</strong>s, there have been extensive revisions to secondary market<br />

disclosure with the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOX) and subsequent regulatory<br />

amendments." Sarbanes-Oxley was enacted to mandate a number of reforms to<br />

enhance corporate responsibility and financial disclosure, and to combat corporate<br />

and accounting fraud. SEC rules since 2002 have included, but are not limited to, 1)<br />

certification of disclosure by the issuer's executive and financial officers, 7 2) new<br />

disclosures regarding audit committee financial experts," 3) requirements regarding<br />

disclosure of off-balance sheet arrangements in MD&A and aggregate contractual<br />

obligations; 73 and 4) electronic filing and web-site posting of requirements for insider<br />

transactions." One question is whether, as a result of SOX requirements, issuers<br />

have been disclosing many more minor announcements that do not materially<br />

impact financial statements, in order to reduce liability risk.<br />

Given the need to defer to decisions by corporate officers as to what<br />

information is material such that it must be disclosed, U.S. regulators have imposed<br />

assurance requirements on corporate officers, which has the effect of deferring to<br />

corporate officers the decision about what information is considered material for<br />

disclosure. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act section 404 directs the SEC to adopt rules<br />

requiring issuers to include in their annual reports "a statement of management's<br />

responsibility for establishing and maintaining adequate internal control over<br />

financial reporting" and assess the effectiveness of those internal controls. 75 The<br />

company's auditors are to attest to and report on this management assessment. 76<br />

The objective of the provisions is to enhance confidence in financial reporting<br />

67. Opinion of the European Economic and Social Committee on the 'Proposal for a Directive of the<br />

European Parliament and of the Council on the Harmonization of Transparency Requirements with Regard<br />

to Information about Issuers whose Securities are Admitted to Trading on a Regulated Market and<br />

Amending Directive 2001/34/EC, O.J. (C 80/128), para. 1.2.<br />

68. Directive 2004/109/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 15 December 2-4 on the<br />

Harmonization of Transparency Requirements in Relation to Information about Issuers whose Securities are<br />

Admitted to Trading on a Regulated Market and amending directive 2001/34/EC, O.J. (L 390), para. 41.<br />

69. Id. pmbl, para. 1. The directive is aimed at greater harmonization of periodic and ongoing<br />

information requirements throughout the Community.<br />

70. Sarbanes-Oxley Act, 15 U.S.C. § 7241 s. 302(a) (2002). For an example, see the 2002 revised<br />

Uniform Securities Act, aimed at further harmonization of federal and state securities law.<br />

71. Sarbanes-Oxley Act, § 7241 s. 3 0 2 (a).<br />

72. Id. §§7241 ss. 302, 7265 s. 407.<br />

73. Id. § 7261 s. 401(a).<br />

74. Securities Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C.A. 15 U.S.C. § 78p s. 16(a) (2002).<br />

75. Sarbanes-Oxley Act, 15 USC §7262.<br />

76. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 891 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:875<br />

because internal controls over that reporting would be effective and timely. 7 The<br />

original compliance date for SOX section 404 has been delayed several times. 78 In<br />

part, the delay has resulted from compliance costs being much greater than<br />

anticipated. The SEC cites a study that found that "second year total costs of<br />

reporting, after initial development of controls reporting, for public companies with<br />

a market capitalization of $75-700 million was on average $900,000.,, 7 '<br />

Smaller companies have had difficulty in working towards compliance with<br />

SOX section 404 rules, specifically because of a lack of guidance in the requirements<br />

in terms of application to smaller companies; a compliance model that discourages<br />

use of business judgment, and a disproportionate cost burden that some scholars<br />

have suggested could pose significant risks to economic growth in United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

capital markets. 0 The SEC Advisory Committee on Smaller Public Companies has<br />

recommended adopting a disclosure system that integrates disclosure rules that<br />

apply to WKSIs, but based on capitalization. 8 ' It also suggests that management<br />

representations as to the effectiveness of internal controls should be sufficient for<br />

micro and small cap issuers, without external audit involvement. 82 The premise is<br />

that micro cap and small cap companies account for 78.5% of all U.S. public<br />

companies, but represent only 6% of total market capitalization, and that the<br />

offering requirements, as well as SOX section 404 requirements, create a<br />

disproportionate compliance burden on smaller issuers. 83<br />

Mote recently, however, the SEC has announced its intention to proceed with<br />

deadlines for SOX section 404 compliance, offering new interpretive guidance aimed<br />

at enabling public companies of all sizes to focus on risk and materiality in evaluating<br />

their disclosure processes and controls, while reducing unnecessary compliance costs<br />

for smaller companies. It also merits note that some market participants, such as<br />

private equity funds, hold smaller issuers to the higher SOX section 404<br />

requirements, even where they have not yet been required to comply under U.S.<br />

securities law, as this serves as a governance check on their activities.<br />

Another example of evolving transparency norms is Australia, which has<br />

embarked on a series of regulatory changes aimed at enhancing disclosure. The<br />

Corporate <strong>Law</strong> Economic Reform Program (Audit Reform and Corporate<br />

Disclosure) Act (CLERP 9) focuses on transparent and open communication to<br />

create equal access to material information, continuous disclosure, financial<br />

reporting, audit reform, and auditor independence and enforcement.' CLERP 9 is<br />

aimed at "new, clear, concise and effective disclosure obligations" in the issuing of<br />

77. SEC Release No. 33-8238, (June 5, 2003) 68 FR 36636; SEC Release No. 34-49884 (June 17, 2004)<br />

69 FR 35083.<br />

78. SEC Release No. 33-8545 (Sept. 22, 2005) 70 FR 11528.<br />

79. SEC Release Nos. 33-8666, 34-53385, Exposure Draft of the Final Report of the SEC Advisory<br />

Committee on Smaller Public Companies (Mar. 3, 2006) at 29.<br />

80. William J. Carney, The Costs of Being Public After Sarbanes-Oxley: The Irony of 'Going Private,<br />

available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=672761; Roberta Romano, The Sarbanes-Oxley Act and the Making of<br />

Quack Corporate Governance, 114 Yale L. J. 1521 (2005).<br />

81. Exposure Draft of the Final Report of the SEC Advisory Committee on Smaller Public<br />

Companies, supra note 79, at 15.<br />

82. Id. at 40-41, 44.<br />

83. Id. at 5,25-50.<br />

84. Corporate <strong>Law</strong> Economic Reform program (Audit Reform and Corporate Disclosure) Act, (July<br />

2004), amending the Corporations Act, 2001, enacted July 2004, http://www.asic.gov.au.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 892 2006-2007


2007<br />

DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT<br />

securities, which includes a new remedy in the form of an infringement notice for<br />

breaches of continuous disclosure obligations."<br />

There are different normative views as to whether a full rules-based system<br />

creates a climate of compliance or generates a "tick-the-box view" of compliance<br />

without market participants really acquiring a sense of responsibility for their<br />

disclosures." One point of divergence is whether principles/standards-based, lesscodified<br />

requirements can better foster a climate of compliance and integrity once<br />

the issuer is known to the market and regulators, and whether the<br />

principles/standards-based approach instills a concern for market participants based<br />

on an enshrined sense of responsibility. One view is that less codification raises the<br />

level of uncertainty for issuers in terms of the standards they must meet; for<br />

investors in determining the availability of a remedy for particular conduct; and for<br />

regulators in allocating resources for compliance and enforcement initiatives. A<br />

different view is that less certainty can mean that issuers and their principal officers<br />

must consciously make disclosure decisions on the basis of standards and their best<br />

judgment on materiality and investor protection.<br />

Given the high level of court deference to securities regulators and the fact that<br />

the courts themselves are not experts, a further question is whether less codification<br />

would really just relegate rule-making in many jurisdictions to securities<br />

administrators, as uncertain standards are enforced at the first instance by regulators<br />

and lack of codification could leave securities regulators as the de facto law-makers.<br />

While there may be some risk of that outcome, one notes that securities regulators<br />

are already rule-makers at first instance, and that a principles/standards-based<br />

approach may shift that slightly by encouraging issuers to cultivate best disclosure<br />

practices. The principles/standards-based approach to disclosure does not eliminate<br />

rules; instead, it reduces the degree of specificity in some instances so that issuers can<br />

develop disclosure practices based on their size, sector, and governance structure.<br />

VI. INTERPLAY BETWEEN BUSINESS JUDGMENT AND DISCLOSURE<br />

OBLIGATIONS<br />

Issuers are required to disclose material information as a condition of access to<br />

capital markets. Determining what information is considered material is, however, a<br />

judgment that is to be made by corporate officers. Hence, statutory standards of<br />

materiality are complied with judgments regarding what aspects of the issuer's<br />

activities or financial condition are material. The interplay between statutory<br />

standards and corporate decisions as to when and what to disclose is a key issue in an<br />

effective disclosure regime.<br />

In considering the relationship between disclosure requirements and the<br />

business judgment rule, it is important to distinguish between the notion of<br />

deference to business judgment and the so-called "business judgment rule" as it has<br />

85. AUSTRL. SEC. & INV. COMM'N, CONTINUOUS DISCLOSURE OBLIGATIONS: INFRINGEMENT<br />

NOTICES 3 (2004),<br />

http://www.asic.gov.au/asic/pdflib.nsf/LookupByFileName/infringement-notice-guidelines.pdf/$file/infring<br />

ementnotice-guidelines.pdf; AUSTRL. SEC. & INV. COMM'N, CORPORATE LAW ECONOMIC REFORM<br />

PROGRAM 4 (2004), http://www.treasury.gov.au/documents/264/PDF/clerp.pdf.<br />

86. Compare, e.g., the approaches of the United <strong>State</strong>s and United Kingdom to compliance.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 893 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:875<br />

been articulated in United <strong>State</strong>s caselaw. In the United <strong>State</strong>s, the business<br />

judgment rule is a rule of "judicial non-review" of business decisions, creating a<br />

rebuttable presumption that directors are meeting their duty of care, and that in<br />

performing their duties, are honest, well-meaning, and their decisions are informed<br />

and rational. The business judgment rule limits judicial review of directors' business<br />

decisions in order to limit the amount of interference in business affairs by the<br />

judiciary. 87 Hence, the rule shields directors from personal liability and shields the<br />

decisions of corporate boards from judicial review.<br />

In Canada, there has been long-standing court deference to business judgments.<br />

More recently, the Supreme Court of Canada recognized a "business judgment rule"<br />

in Canadian corporate law. Unlike the U.S. rule, Canada's approach is aimed at<br />

providing a defence to duly diligent directors from allegations that they have failed<br />

to meet their statutory and common law obligations to act in the best interests of the<br />

corporation. 88 There must first be evidence that corporate officers have been duly<br />

diligent. Such deference, however, is complicated where there are statutory<br />

standards that corporate officers are to meet. The Ontario Court of Appeal in Kerr<br />

v. Danier Leather held that the business judgment rule applies to director decisions<br />

with respect to primary market disclosure obligations." It held that reasonableness<br />

is the centerpiece of the business judgment rule, involving a range of<br />

reasonableness. ° There are important differences between the United <strong>State</strong>s' and<br />

Canadian tests and thus a key issue is how business judgment is treated when<br />

measured against statutory disclosure requirements in securities laws. 9 '<br />

Clearly, there are business judgments involved in an issuer determining what is<br />

considered material information. Given that directors and officers have the greatest<br />

knowledge and understanding of their business, operations, and capital, they are the<br />

most likely to be able to determine accurately what is or is not material information.<br />

Disclosure decisions can involve difficult business judgments, and in distinguishing<br />

between material fact and material change reporting in Canadian securities law, the<br />

determination of where particular information fits within those differing obligations<br />

is arguably a matter of business judgment. However, such business judgment bumps<br />

up against clear statutory disclosure requirements. Where the law specifies a<br />

particular disclosure, there is no business judgment to be made: the issuer must<br />

comply with the law. It is where judgment is called for that market participants may<br />

need some guidance of the scope of any deference that may be granted.<br />

The judgment issue is complicated when there are determinations about when<br />

to disclose material facts, such as early merger discussions, transactions under<br />

negotiation, or consideration of moving into new markets or different product lines.<br />

Disclosure too early may be highly premature and have a negative effect on a<br />

proposed transaction or direction that the issuer is considering taking. It may also<br />

cause investors to make decisions prior to the particular matter having actually<br />

crystallized, which in turn could harm investors' interests and create uncertainty in<br />

the market." While the issuer can make confidential disclosure to the regulator in<br />

87. Aronson v. Lewis, 473 A.2d 805, 812 (Del. 1984); Sinclair Oil Corp. v. Levien, 280 A.2d 717, 720<br />

(Del. 1971).<br />

88. Peoples Dep't. Stores Inc. v. Wise, [2004] 3 S.C.R. 461 (Can.).<br />

89. Kerr, supra note 57.<br />

90. Id.<br />

91. Hopefully this will be a question that the Supreme Court of Canada clarifies on appeal.<br />

92. See Re YBM Magnex Int'l Inc., [2003] 26 O.S.C.B. 5285, para. 29 (Ont. Sec. Comm'n.).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 894 2006-2007


2007<br />

DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT<br />

many jurisdictions, this does not prevent the disclosure from entering the market, it<br />

only delays the release. Where early discussions regarding transactions or mergers<br />

do not crystallize but are disclosed on a delayed basis, this could send<br />

misinformation to the market. Another view is that early disclosure does not send<br />

misinformation, particularly if the disclosure is accurately couched in language that<br />

reflects the degree of uncertainty. It is the information being presented as more<br />

certain than it actually is that creates misinformation. If this problem were<br />

addressed, early disclosure could have an explanatory and mitigating effect on<br />

market disruption.<br />

However, if deference to business judgments is too high, it will create incentives<br />

for issuers not to disclose and then seek the protection of the business judgment rule<br />

to justify business decisions not to disclose material changes. In turn, this may<br />

prevent material information from being disclosed in a timely manner and would<br />

create barriers for investors in establishing claims of breach of statutory disclosure<br />

requirements.<br />

As a result, some express statutory language addressing this issue may be<br />

warranted, as business judgment is an area that is likely to generate different judicial<br />

approaches to the deference question across jurisdictions. This differing approach<br />

may result in increased uncertainty for all market participants. The objective of the<br />

disclosure requirement is to ensure that the issuer deals with disclosure of good news<br />

and bad news with equal urgency. Deference to business judgment should apply<br />

only to judgments that are made on a reasonable basis after a duly diligent process.<br />

Given current information asymmetries, it may be necessary to place an onus on the<br />

issuer's officers to establish their due diligence, as has occurred in the context of<br />

takeover bid cases. Any deference given as a judicial interpretation tool or device<br />

should be carefully limited so as not to detract from both the express disclosure<br />

requirements in securities law and the goals of investor protection, market efficiency,<br />

and public confidence in capital markets.<br />

VII. DEVELOPMENT AN ELECTRONIC INTEGRATED MARKET<br />

DISCLOSURE DOCUMENT<br />

Any initiatives to modernize disclosure as a public policy instrument should<br />

build in mechanisms that test the effectiveness of whether outcomes of proposed<br />

rule changes are clear and likely. One Canadian securities regulator has observed<br />

that rules should also be tested for their neutrality in order to not favor particular<br />

types of market participants, for their flexibility in order to require market<br />

participants to exercise judgment and place responsibility on officers to establish and<br />

apply adequate systems and controls to meet regulatory requirements, for scope so<br />

that rules should prescribe only what is necessary to achieve the intended outcome,<br />

and for clarity so that the rules are accessible, understandable, and able to be<br />

applied practically. 93<br />

One option to address many of the issues raised in this article is to locate<br />

disclosure in one "living" electronic integrated market disclosure document (IMDD)<br />

that investors can access at any point in the life cycle of the issuer, whether it is<br />

93. British Columbia Securities Commission Home Page, http://www.bcsc.ca.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 895 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:875<br />

making an offer of securities to the market or meeting its continuous disclosure<br />

obligations." ' The integrated market disclosure document (IMDD) could combine<br />

financial statements, MD&As, AIFs, and proxy circulars into one document. These<br />

financial and other disclosures are called by different names in different jurisdictions,<br />

but they increasingly align in the nature of their disclosure requirements globally and<br />

thus could be integrated into a living IMDD.<br />

Such an integrated disclosure document could contain four parts. The first part<br />

of a new IMDD could be an executive summary of no more than four to five pages,<br />

with a substantive and informative summary of material information regarding the<br />

issuer conveying in brief, non-technical language the essential characteristics and<br />

risks associated with the issuer and the securities. Modeled after the European<br />

Union summary document, it would provide specific references to relevant materials<br />

in the remainder of the document. The executive summary would not provide "full<br />

disclosure," as that is what the remainder of the document would provide; however,<br />

it would be fulsome because it would flag the material information. This part would<br />

be required to meet the threshold of reporting material information in a way that<br />

investors could both rely on the information and seek remedies where the issuer<br />

failed to flag it. It could caution that investors are to make any investment decisions<br />

based on the IMDD as a whole, and that no civil liability will attach to any person<br />

solely on the basis of the summary, unless it is misleading, inaccurate, or inconsistent<br />

when read together with other parts of the IMDD.<br />

The second part of the proposed IMDD would contain the financial statements,<br />

as well as information that is currently disclosed in the AIF, providing extensive and<br />

substantive financial and operational disclosure. While an effort would be made<br />

towards plain language disclosure, this part would provide the level of detail<br />

necessary for analysts and other market participants to make an informed<br />

assessment of the issuer, and provide an integrated snapshot of the issuer's capital,<br />

business, and operations.<br />

The third part of the IMDD would contain MD&A-type descriptions by senior<br />

officers, but would directly reference previous parts to eliminate duplicative<br />

information, with a specified standard on which to measure the quality of disclosure.<br />

The new Compensation Disclosure and Analysis (CD&A) required in the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s (effective in 2006) could also form part of this section. 9 " It may also be timely<br />

to require disclosures in this part for corporate social and environmental<br />

responsibility measures, as part of the corporate governance disclosures. Corporate<br />

social responsibility disclosures are increasingly prevalent in EU member states and<br />

other countries. Canada's requirements in this respect are minimal at best, although<br />

a number of issuers, particularly in the resource sector, are routinely disclosing<br />

environmental sustainability measures. This corporate social and environmental<br />

responsibility disclosure could be pegged to a standard developed by private actors,<br />

such as the "comply or explain" standard pegged to the principles of the Global<br />

Compact, or it could merely impose a general requirement to disclose practices in<br />

respect of the issuer's social and environmental responsibility practices.<br />

94. I first proposed this idea as part of the background research report for the Task Force to<br />

Modernize Securities <strong>Law</strong> in Canada, see SARRA, supra note 1, at 11-12.<br />

95. SEC News Release, SEC votes to Adopt Changes to Disclosure Requirements Concerning<br />

Executive Compensation and Related Matters, http://www.sec.gov/news/press/2006/2006-123.htm.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 896 2006-2007


2007<br />

DISCLOSURE AS A PUBLIC POLICY INSTRUMENT<br />

The final part of the IMDD would comprise Future Oriented Financial<br />

Information (FOFI), separated because of the particular nature of forecast<br />

disclosure. While FOFI would be optional, as it is under many current systems, it<br />

too would have clear standards, whether based on a reasonableness standard or<br />

reasonable investigation standard.<br />

Subsequent material change reporting would then be integrated directly into<br />

the IMDD as one document, flagging the date of the change in disclosure. Press<br />

releases and the revised IMDD with the material change incorporated would clearly<br />

signal to market participants at the front of the document the nature of the change<br />

and location in the document. The IMDD as a whole would be the living disclosure<br />

document, and would include electronic "tags" specifying when the particular<br />

material change or information disclosure was integrated into the document.<br />

This notion of a dynamic current and accessible document is possible given<br />

technological developments. Instead of investors having to access numerous<br />

documents, plus trying to ascertain whether there have been material change<br />

reports, all information publicly available to the market would be contained in one<br />

document at all times, including a "last updated" reference. This model would place<br />

the emphasis on disclosure to meet the principal goals of informing and protecting<br />

investors, while generating efficiencies in capital markets. The transaction costs of<br />

converting to a single document would eventually be offset by the streamlined<br />

nature of the disclosure.<br />

The IMDD could be held to a standard of disclosure of all material<br />

information, thus aligning many jurisdictions. The uniformity in requirements would<br />

promote harmonization of standards and certainty for issuers. A less rigorous option<br />

is that the IMDD would hold the issuer to a standard of disclosure of material<br />

information at the time the IMDD is first presented to the market, with material<br />

changes integrated on an ongoing basis, and then requiring a semi-annual update to<br />

include all material information, with the summary clearly specifying the last update<br />

period. Micro and small cap issuers could be required to undertake the update<br />

annually if there are concerns about the costs of semi-annual compliance for these<br />

issuers.<br />

The proposed IMDD does meet a number of the indicia of effective rule<br />

changes. It would be flexible, in terms of issuers creating an IMDD that allows the<br />

issuer to meet a standard of disclosure. It would eliminate duplication in primary<br />

and secondary market disclosures. It would provide all market participants with<br />

single portal access to current material information about the issuer. It could be<br />

designed with stock exchanges so that issuers are required to meet only one set of<br />

disclosure standards.<br />

VIII. CONCLUSION<br />

This article raises a number of issues in respect of disclosure, particularly with<br />

the growth of global capital markets. Disclosure is the public policy instrument of<br />

choice for most countries for the protection of investors and the efficiency of capital<br />

markets. However, with the rapid changes in the number and types of securities<br />

offerings, the exponential growth in web-based paperless disclosure, and the<br />

international nature of securities trading, there needs to be further exploration of<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 897 2006-2007


898 TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL VOL. 42:875<br />

how regulatory structures can adjust to ensure that disclosure requirements continue<br />

to foster fair and efficient capital markets.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 898 2006-2007


Avoidance of Pre-Bankruptcy Transactions in<br />

Multinational Bankruptcy Cases<br />

JAY LAWRENCE WESTBROOK*<br />

SUMMARY<br />

I. B A CK G RO U N D ..................................................................................................... 900<br />

I1. FRAM ING THE PROBLEM .................................................................................... 900<br />

A . Choice of Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong> ........................................................................ 900<br />

B . N onbankruptcy L aw ................................................................................... 904<br />

III. T H E FREN CH C A SE ............................................................................................. 905<br />

A. The Presumption Against Extraterritoriality ............................................ 906<br />

1. Significant C ontacts .............................................................................. 906<br />

2. C ongressional Intent ............................................................................ 907<br />

3 . C o m ity ................................................................................................... 908<br />

IV . M ID LA N D ............................................................................................................. 910<br />

V . A L SA BA H ............................................................................................................ 911<br />

V I. O NE STEP FA RTHER ........................................................................................... 913<br />

A. Conflict Between Avoidance <strong>Law</strong> and Other <strong>Law</strong> Governing the<br />

C hallenged Transaction .............................................................................. 913<br />

B. Nonbankruptcy Avoidance <strong>Law</strong> ................................................................ 914<br />

V II. C O N C LU SIO N ....................................................................................................... 915<br />

From the perspective of planning commercial transactions, the application of<br />

the avoiding powers may be the single most important aspect of multinational<br />

insolvency/bankruptcy cases.' Yet there have been remarkably few reported cases<br />

dealing with those issues. The present author was guilty of an article on the subject<br />

* Benno C. Schmidt Chair of Business <strong>Law</strong>, The University of Texas School of <strong>Law</strong>. I am indebted to<br />

Look Chan Ho for a helpful critique. I am grateful to Erin Murdock, Texas '08, for expert research<br />

assistance. I must claim the remaining errors.<br />

1. Although I use the United <strong>State</strong>s term "bankruptcy" throughout, the analysis is meant to apply<br />

primarily to corporate insolvency proceedings.<br />

899<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 899 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:899<br />

some fifteen years ago . Very few cases have been reported since that time, until the<br />

three fraudulent conveyance cases I discuss in this article. The French case is a<br />

Court of Appeals case that applies United <strong>State</strong>s law to avoid a pre-bankruptcy<br />

transfer of real estate in Bermuda.' In the Midland Euro Exchange case, the Los<br />

Angeles bankruptcy court comes to the opposite conclusion about a transnational<br />

payment in the context of a Ponzi scheme.' In the third case, Al Sabah, the Privy<br />

Council applied Cayman Islands law to permit a Bahamian trustee in bankruptcy to<br />

undo two Cayman Islands trusts Relatively speaking, our cup runneth over.<br />

I. BACKGROUND<br />

As I have noted in a prior paper for the Academy, many issues in a<br />

multinational bankruptcy case require two distinct choice-of-law analyses: one to<br />

determine the proper nonbankruptcy law and the other to choose the applicable<br />

bankruptcy law. 6 Thus, for example, nonbankruptcy law might determine if a party<br />

has a valid contract claim against the debtor in bankruptcy, while bankruptcy law<br />

would determine the priority, if any, that claim would receive in a bankruptcy<br />

distribution. The contract law would be chosen by "the proper law of the contract" 7<br />

in most cases, while the choice of applicable bankruptcy law would depend on<br />

whether the jurisdiction followed a more territorial or a more universalist approach<br />

in multinational bankruptcy cases. 8<br />

II.<br />

FRAMING THE PROBLEM<br />

A. Choice of Bankruptcy <strong>Law</strong><br />

The ancient law review article I mentioned above was devoted exclusively to<br />

the second determination, the choice of bankruptcy law. In that article, I surveyed<br />

the few existing cases concerning choice of law for avoidance actions and performed<br />

2. Jay L. Westbrook, Choice of Avoidance <strong>Law</strong> in Global Insolvencies, 17 BROOK. J. INT'L L. 499<br />

(1991) [hereinafter Westbrook, Global].<br />

3. In re French, 440 F.3d 145, 148 (4th Cir. 2006), cert. denied, 127 S. Ct. 72 (2006).<br />

4. In re Midland Euro Exch. 347 B.R. 708, 708-09 (Bankr. C.D. Cal. 2006).<br />

5. Al Sabah v. Grupo Torras S.A. [2005] UKPC 1, [2005] 2 W.L.R. 904.<br />

6. Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook, Universalism and Choice of <strong>Law</strong>, 23 PENN ST. INT'L L. REV. 625 (2005)<br />

[hereinafter Westbrook, Universalism]. Cf In re Aerovias Nacionales de Colombia S.A. Avianca and<br />

Avianca, Inc., 345 B.R. 120 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 2006) (applying nonbankruptcy law of Columbia, without<br />

noting the bankruptcy/nonbankruptcy distinction).<br />

7. Westbrook, Universalism, supra note 6, at 634.<br />

8. See generally, AM. LAW INST., PRINCIPLES OF COOPERATION AMONG THE NAFTA COUNTRIES 8<br />

(2003) [hereinafter ALI Principles] (I had the privilege of serving as the U.S. Reporter for the project). See<br />

also Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook, A Global Solution to Multinational Default, 98 MICH. L. REV. 2276, 2297<br />

(2000); Donald T. Trautman, Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook & Emmanuel Gaillard, Four Models for<br />

International Bankruptcy, 41 AM. J. COMP. L. 573, 576-78 (1994)[hereinafter Four Models]; Evelyn H.<br />

Biery et al., A Look At Transnational Insolvencies And Chapter 15 Of The Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention<br />

And Consumer Protection Act Of 2005, 47 B.C. L. REV. 23, 26-30 (2005). Lord Hoffman has recently<br />

written an eloquent and insightful statement of the basis for a universalist approach. Cambridge Gas<br />

Transport Corporation v. The Official Committee of Unsecured Creditors (Navigator Holdings PLC)<br />

[2006] UKPC 26, paras. 16-20 (appeal taken from Isle of Man).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 900 2006-2007


2007<br />

AVOIDANCE OF PRE-BANKRUPTCY TRANSACTIONS<br />

a detailed analysis as to the choice of the proper avoidance law in multinational<br />

cases. I refer the reader to that article for a more elaborate discussion.<br />

Because all three of the recent cases have involved what Americans would call<br />

a "fraudulent conveyance," I will focus on that aspect of the problem. We start with<br />

the fact that a court following a traditional territorial approach to multinational<br />

bankruptcies will have difficulty fashioning a defensible choice-of-law rule for<br />

avoidance of multinational transactions. Territorialists grab what local assets are<br />

available and apply local law to them. They then distribute any proceeds of an<br />

avoiding action under the local priority system.' They would normally not seek to<br />

recover assets located in foreign jurisdictions, but they may control assets that have<br />

arguably been transferred in fraud of creditors. The literature does not reveal any<br />

coherent approach to the application of foreign avoidance law under a territorialist<br />

system.<br />

However, courts in the United <strong>State</strong>s and a number of other countries are<br />

moving in the direction of a modified universalism in multinational bankruptcies,<br />

seeking to cooperate with other courts in achieving a pragmatic result as close as<br />

possible to the ideal of a single worldwide proceeding." Those courts are forced to<br />

consider which country's bankruptcy laws should be applied to a particular issue in a<br />

multinational bankruptcy system. For example, if a creditor subject to personal<br />

jurisdiction in two countries, such as a multinational bank, engages in behavior that<br />

violates the moratorium (stay) of the country where a bankruptcy proceeding is<br />

pending, yet the behavior takes place entirely in the second country where there is<br />

no proceeding, which law should apply to the creditor's conduct?<br />

The most difficult choice-of-law issue is determining which avoidance law to<br />

apply to a given pre-bankruptcy transaction. The first step in fashioning a sound<br />

approach is to understand that the avoidance provisions in every country reflect a<br />

balance between two conflicting values:<br />

a) the need to return to the estate certain property transferred prior to<br />

bankruptcy for redistribution according to the statutory scheme of priority; 3<br />

b) the need to avoid imposing too much uncertainty in the marketplace with<br />

regard to transactions that are normally unobjectionable.<br />

Countries draw the balance quite differently at the margins. Almost all<br />

bankruptcy laws would permit avoidance of a gift given with the intent to evade<br />

creditors at a time when the transferor was insolvent and the transferee had the<br />

9. See generally Lynn M. LoPucki, The Case for Cooperative Territoriality in International Bankruptcy,<br />

98 MICH. L. REV. 2216, 2218-21 (2000).<br />

10. Id. at 2219.<br />

11. See ALI Principles, supra note 8, at 3. But see McMahon v. McGrath (In re HIH Casualty and<br />

General Insurance Ltd.) [2006] EWCA (Civ) 372, [2006] All. E.R. (D) 65 (Jun) (denial of cooperation with<br />

Australian reorganization scheme).<br />

12. ALI Principles, supra note 8, Principle 5 and Illus., at 49-50.<br />

13. This factor is often stated as satisfying the goal of "equality of distribution," but in fact distribution<br />

is highly unequal in all systems because of statutory priorities. At most, equality means nondiscrimination<br />

within a class of creditors. See R. J. Mokal, CORPORATE INSOLVENCY LAW: THEORY AND APPLICATION<br />

xx (2005); L. C. Ho, On Pari Passu, Equality and Hotchpot in Cross-Border Insolvency, 1 LLOYD'S MAR. &<br />

COMMERCIAL LAW QUARTERLY 95, (2003), 5-7, available at<br />

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=365660; Westbrook, Global, supra note 2, at 506-07.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 901 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:899<br />

intent to cooperate in the evasion. 14 However, jurisdictions are sharply divided as to<br />

the relevance of the transferee's state of mind-some regarding it as a crucial<br />

element or defense, while others are prepared to avoid the transfer regardless of the<br />

transferee's knowledge or intent. 5 Where there is some consideration for a transfer<br />

by an insolvent, but what the transferor gets falls well short of equaling the value of<br />

the property, some laws would make avoidance dependent upon the state of mind<br />

and knowledge of the transferor, the transferee, or both. 6 Other laws (for example,<br />

the Bankruptcy Code in the United <strong>State</strong>s 7 ) would for the most part ignore the state<br />

of mind of either party in determining avoidability.<br />

The case for avoidance is often compelling. A pre-bankruptcy transfer by an<br />

insolvent debtor for little or no consideration may well impact the rights of creditors<br />

in a serious way and often will be ill-motivated in fact. On the other hand,<br />

fraudulent conveyance laws often reach far back in time, and avoidance of a transfer<br />

made to an innocent party years before bankruptcy may impose a serious and costly<br />

uncertainty on the market and be seen as quite unfair to the transferee.' 8<br />

It will fairly often be true that one country with significant contacts with a<br />

payment or other transaction would hold it avoidable while a second relevant<br />

country would not. In this common situation, which law should be applied? I have<br />

argued that those courts following the approach of modified universalism should<br />

apply the avoidance law of the debtor's home country. 9 In broad and brutal<br />

summary of a complex analysis, there are two key reasons for this conclusion. The<br />

first reason is that no other rule can be predictable and transparent in its<br />

application. 0 The modern conflicts literature has long since demonstrated that a rule<br />

depending on the "place" in which the transaction occurred is manipulable and<br />

unpredictable. 2 ' In every difficult case, the transaction has elements in more than<br />

one jurisdiction; therefore, it is easy to choose either place as the relevant location<br />

and apply its law.<br />

In reaction to this defect, modern conflicts analysis looks at significant conflicts<br />

and the interests of the states involved. 22 However, modern analysis applied on a<br />

case by case basis can also raise serious problems of predictability, 23 making it hard<br />

for parties to know if their transactions might run afoul of bankruptcy laws in<br />

14. See generally J. H. DALHUISEN, DALHUISEN ON INTERNATIONAL INSOLVENCY AND<br />

BANKRUPTCY, Vol 1, Part II, § 1.01 (1986). I deliberately write a bit loosely, because the various laws are<br />

endlessly nuanced as to intent and knowledge.<br />

15. ld. at § 1.04.<br />

16. Id.<br />

17. 11 U.S.C. §§ 548, 550 (2006).<br />

18. One might think of the debtor's children being asked to return their bicycles, dolls, and action<br />

figures-but, then again, one might think of the debtor's spouse being allowed to keep a chateau in the<br />

south of France.<br />

19. See Westbrook, Global, supra note 2, at 500.<br />

20. Id. at 530.<br />

21. RUSSELL WEINTRAUB, COMMENTARY ON THE CONFLICT OF LAWS § 1.5 (2001); LUTHER L.<br />

McDOUGAL, III, ROBERT L. FELIX, RALPH U. WHITTEN, AMERICAN CONFLICTS LAW § 2 (2001).<br />

22. See BRAINERD CURRIE, SELECTED ESSAYS ON THE CONFLICT OF LAWS 180 (1963).<br />

23. See Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook, Extraterritoriality, Conflicts of <strong>Law</strong>s, and Transnational Regulation<br />

of Business, 25 TEX. INT'L L. J. 71, 87 (1990) [hereinafter Westbrook, Extraterritoriality]; Ralph U. Whitten,<br />

U.S. Conflict-of-<strong>Law</strong>s Doctrine and Forum Shopping, International and Domestic (Revisited), 37 TEX.<br />

INT'L L. J. 559, 572 (2002); Ralph U. Whitten, Curing the Deficiencies of the Conflicts Revolution: A<br />

Proposal for National Legislation on Choice of <strong>Law</strong>, Jurisdiction, and Judgments, 37 WILLAMETrE L. REV.<br />

259, 277 (2001).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 902 2006-2007


2007<br />

AVOIDANCE OF PRE-BANKRUPTCY TRANSACTIONS<br />

another country. A home-country rule provides the best result we can currently<br />

hope to achieve in that it is relatively difficult to manipulate and produces<br />

reasonably predictable outcomes. 24 No other approach can produce as good results<br />

at an acceptable cost. 25<br />

The second reason for applying home-country law turns on the fact that the<br />

whole purpose of avoiding powers in a bankruptcy proceeding is to redistribute the<br />

debtor's assets according to certain statutory priorities. 26 Because of the link<br />

between avoidance and priority, an interests analysis supports a home-country rule.<br />

Let's take the example of a transfer of personal property made by X, a citizen and<br />

resident of Country A, to Y, a citizen and resident of Country B. At all times the<br />

property is located in Country B. Shortly after the transfer, X files for bankruptcy in<br />

Country A. There is no bankruptcy filed as to X in Country B. The bankruptcy law<br />

of Country A provides that all bankruptcy distributions will go to Creditor Group 1,<br />

including all proceeds of avoidance actions. Country B's bankruptcy law gives all<br />

such distributions to Creditor Group 2. The transfer is not avoidable under the laws<br />

of Country A, but is avoidable under the laws of Country B. We may also assume<br />

that there are creditors from each creditor group in each of the two countries.<br />

In this situation, it seems obvious that the Country A court should refuse a<br />

request by X's trustee in bankruptcy to avoid the transaction. It cannot be avoided<br />

under the local law in Country A. If the Country A bankruptcy court avoids the<br />

transfer by applying the law of Country B, the result would be a windfall for<br />

Creditor Group 1, even though neither country would avoid the transaction for the<br />

benefit of Group 1. Nothing would go to Creditor Group 2 because of the priority<br />

24. Professor LoPucki would disagree, because he regards the home-country court determination as<br />

inherently unpredictable. Lynn M. LoPucki, Universalism Unravels, 79 AM. BANKR. L.J. 143, 158-59<br />

(2005). I have suggested that modified universalism increases the predictability of the forum that will be<br />

chosen, and therefore the law that will be applied, even though it falls well short of the universalist ideal.<br />

Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook, Multinational Financial Distress: The Last Hurrah Of Territorialism, 41 TEX.<br />

INT'L L.J. 321, 327 (2006); Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook, Locating the Eye of the Financial Storm, 32 BROOK.<br />

INT'L L.J._(forthcoming 2007) (copy on file with the author) [hereinafter Westbrook, Storm].<br />

25. It must be conceded that a fairly predictable result might be obtainable by adopting the<br />

unfortunate rule in the European Insolvency Regulation, but only at a considerable cost. Commission<br />

Regulation 1346/2000, art. 13, 2000 O.J. (L 160) 1. The effect of the rule is that the transaction will often<br />

escape avoidance unless it would be avoidable under the laws of both the home country and the country<br />

whose laws otherwise govern the transaction. (The actual language is opaque, but the foregoing is a<br />

reasonable interpretation). See Miguel Virgos & Etienne Schmidt, Report on the Convention on<br />

Insolvency Proceedings, paras. 35-39. The effect of such a rule must be to narrow greatly the applicability<br />

of the avoiding powers and thus weaken the policies of fairness and priority that underlie them.<br />

Westbrook, Global, supra note 2, at 519, n.82; Four Models, supra note 8, at 586.<br />

26. Professors Duggan and Telfer, discussing Canadian law, draw a sharp distinction between<br />

preference and fraudulent conveyance law. Canadian Preference <strong>Law</strong> Reform, 42 TEX. J. INT'L L.J. 661 (<br />

2007). They view the former as having the purpose stated in the text, but understand fraudulent<br />

conveyance law to be directed at protecting each individual creditor against debtor wrongdoing. While I<br />

agree with them with regard to fraudulent conveyance laws operative outside of bankruptcy. See<br />

DALHUISEN, supra note 14. 1 think the purpose of fraudulent conveyance avoidance in bankruptcy<br />

necessarily becomes collective and focused on the publicly determined priority system. Our views may<br />

differ in part because in the United <strong>State</strong>s preference recovery is also available outside of bankruptcy as<br />

against insiders, removing one of the distinctions that influences their views. Unif. Fraudulent Transfer<br />

Act § 5(b). 7A U.L.A. 2 (2006). In addition, the seminal fraudulent conveyance case, Twyne's Case, 3<br />

Coke 806, 76 Eng. Rep. 809 (1601), involved a preferential payment, as did the famous (or infamous) case<br />

of Dean v. Davis in the United <strong>State</strong>s Supreme Court, 242 U.S. 438 (1916). Those cases suggest the close<br />

association of the two doctrines, even though they have diverged in many ways.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 903 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:899<br />

system in Country A. The lawmakers in Country A expressly decided that avoidance<br />

in such a case as this would impose excessive costs on the commercial community,<br />

even though the result would benefit their favored Creditor Group 1. On the other<br />

hand, the lawmakers in Country B overcame any concerns about commercial effects<br />

because of the perceived importance of protecting Creditor Group 2. They seem to<br />

have no concern for Creditor Group 1. Country B lawmakers might even protest<br />

imposing costs on their commercial community to produce proceeds for Group 1.<br />

Neither country's interests would be served by applying Country B's avoidance law<br />

in this case. If we make Creditor Group I secured creditors and Group 2 employees<br />

or taxing authorities, the example is not unrealistic, albeit greatly simplified.<br />

This example illustrates that the best rule for choice of avoiding powers is the<br />

law of the country that will distribute the proceeds of any avoidance recovery. 7 In<br />

an ideal universalist system, that court would be the home-country court for all<br />

creditors throughout the world. Thus the powers would be used when the recoveries<br />

would benefit those who were given priority under the home-country's laws. But<br />

universalism is currently only an ideal. A pragmatic court committed to modified<br />

universalism, such as we find in the United <strong>State</strong>s, should try to come as close to the<br />

universalist result as it practically can. " Thus, it should generally choose the<br />

avoiding power of the home-country court: the transaction is avoidable if, and only<br />

if, it is avoidable under home-country law. Only one of the three cases I discuss<br />

came to that result, although it has the most important precedential force under<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s law.<br />

B. Nonbankruptcy <strong>Law</strong><br />

Ordinarily, this part of the analysis follows the same path as in a nonbankruptcy<br />

context, using the choice-of-law rules generally applied in the jurisdiction to<br />

determine if local law or some other law should apply to the nonbankruptcy<br />

elements of the case. As noted above, in the instance of an ordinary contract claim<br />

filed in the bankruptcy case, the proper law of the contract determines the validity<br />

and amount of the claim, while bankruptcy law determines its priority. 29<br />

Occasionally, the problem becomes more complicated because the bankruptcy<br />

law reflects a policy different from nonbankruptcy law. For example, in a purely<br />

domestic case within the United <strong>State</strong>s, nonbankruptcy law may give landlords a<br />

much bigger claim than United <strong>State</strong>s bankruptcy law will permit." The bankruptcy<br />

law simply overrides the nonbankruptcy law in that case. But if the nonbankruptcy<br />

law is that of another country, the correct answer may not be so clear. The French<br />

case does not appear to raise such an instance, but it suggests how the problem can<br />

arise. I will address that point later in this article.<br />

27. This article does not address the particularly tricky problem that arises when the debtor's COMI<br />

has allegedly changed since the transfer under attack. For a general discussion of COMI and its<br />

manipulation, see Westbrook, Storm, supra note 24, at 24-25.<br />

28. One example of a pragmatic exception would be a refusal to avoid a payment to a small local<br />

creditor in another jurisdiction, where local interests might be too gravely hurt by the threat of distant<br />

litigation. Westbrook, Global, supra note 2, at 531.<br />

29. Westbrook, Universalism, supra note 6, at 634. See generally Rosalind Mason, Choice of <strong>Law</strong> in<br />

Cross-Border Insolvencies: Matters of Substance and Procedure, 9 JNSOLV. L.J. 69 (2001).<br />

30. United <strong>State</strong>s Bankruptcy Code, 11 U.S.C. § 502(b)(6) [hereinafter BC] (limiting the amount a<br />

lessor may claim in bankruptcy).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 904 2006-2007


2007<br />

AVOIDANCE OF PRE-BANKRUPTCY TRANSACTIONS<br />

A second relevance of nonbankruptcy law is found in avoidance statutes that<br />

may be used without a pending bankruptcy proceeding. A well-known example is<br />

the Uniform Fraudulent Transfer Act 3 ' in the United <strong>State</strong>s. It is a uniform law<br />

adopted in most states that can be used by a single creditor to avoid a fraudulent<br />

conveyance and to reap the recovery for the payment of that creditor's debt. I<br />

address that wrinkle in the discussion of Al Sabah below.<br />

III. THE FRENCH CASE 32<br />

The facts in French were simple. Mrs. French gave the deed to her Bermuda<br />

real estate to her children at a Christmas party in 1981. However, the children failed<br />

to record the deed at that time, apparently to avoid taxes. In mid-2000, the children<br />

became concerned about her declining financial situation and filed the deed. Mrs.<br />

French then became the subject of an involuntary Chapter 7 (liquidation) petition in<br />

October of that year. Her trustee in bankruptcy brought an action to avoid the<br />

transfer as a fraudulent conveyance. 3 All the parties were citizens and residents of<br />

the United <strong>State</strong>s at all times. 34<br />

Because the United <strong>State</strong>s Bankruptcy Code treats the transfer as having<br />

occurred on the date of recordation, the transfer fell within the one-year avoidance<br />

period for fraudulent conveyances under section 548 of the Code. 35 The trustee in<br />

bankruptcy apparently did not claim an actual intent to defraud creditors, but rather<br />

"constructive fraud," similar to the British idea of a "transaction at an undervalue." 36<br />

Absent actual intent to defraud, the most commonly invoked avoidable conveyance<br />

attack in the United <strong>State</strong>s contains two required elements: the debtor-transferor<br />

was insolvent at the time of the transfer and the transfer was for less than<br />

"reasonably equivalent value. 3 7 Here both elements were conceded. Thus if section<br />

548 applied to this transaction, it was voidable and the transferees could be required<br />

to reconvey the property to the trustee in bankruptcy. 38 On the other hand, it was<br />

assumed that Bermuda law required an actual intent to defraud creditors as a<br />

condition of avoidance of a conveyance, so the transfer would not be avoidable if<br />

Bermuda law applied.<br />

The Court of Appeals affirmed the actions of the lower courts by finding that<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s law applied and the transaction should be avoided. In determining<br />

that the United <strong>State</strong>s fraudulent conveyance provision applied to the transfer of the<br />

31. Unif. Fraudulent Transfer Act, ULA § 7(a)(1), 7A U.L.A. 2 (2006).<br />

32. In re French, 440 F.3d 145 (4th Cir. 2006), cert. denied, 127 S. Ct. 72 (2006).<br />

33. Id. at 148-49.<br />

34. Id. at 150.<br />

35. 11 U.S.C. § 548(a)(1) (one-year reachback when the French bankruptcy was filed; now two years).<br />

Section 548(d)(1) of the Bankruptcy Code provides that, for the purposes of section 548, a transfer takes<br />

place when it is so "perfected" that it cannot be attacked under non-bankruptcy law by a bona fide<br />

purchaser for value. It appears there was no dispute in French about the fact that this transfer would be<br />

held to be within a year of the October, 2000, petition, so presumably recordation is necessary under<br />

Bermuda law to prevent attack on a transfer by a bona fide purchaser. Thus Bermuda nonbankruptcy law<br />

was tacitly applied as to the perfection of a real estate transfer.<br />

36. French, 440 F.3d at 148.<br />

37. 11 U.S.C. § 548(a)(1)(B). Other grounds include undercapitalization.<br />

38. 11 U.S.C. § 550(a)(1).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 905 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:899<br />

Bermuda property, the court focused on the applicability of the "presumption<br />

against extraterritorial effect" and on comity among courts.39<br />

A. The Presumption Against Extraterritoriality<br />

It is worth noting that the court implicitly began with the assumption that<br />

section 548 applies in any United <strong>State</strong>s bankruptcy case. It then had to determine if<br />

that assumption was inaccurate here because of the so-called presumption against<br />

extraterritoriality. The United <strong>State</strong>s Supreme Court has said the presumption<br />

represents a "longstanding principle of American law 'that legislation of Congress,<br />

unless a contrary intent appears, is meant to apply only within the territorial<br />

4°<br />

jurisdiction of the United <strong>State</strong>s.' The Court's rule could be understood as<br />

requiring Congress to state explicitly that each provision it enacts applies to foreign<br />

transactions if it wishes that provision to have effect where any foreign element is<br />

found. 4 ' However, the lower courts have generally interpreted the presumption<br />

more narrowly. 42 They have done so in two ways. First, they have applied a choiceof-law<br />

analysis to determine if the conduct is "extraterritorial." If not, the<br />

presumption does not apply. 3 Second, they have held the presumption to be<br />

overcome where they find that Congress intended the provision to apply on the facts<br />

presented. They ascertain the Congressional intent from the language of the<br />

provision and from the policy behind the provision. ' The French court used both<br />

methods.<br />

1. Significant Contacts<br />

The court first counted and weighed contacts in classic American choice-of-law<br />

analysis. It found that the great majority of important contacts were in the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s, including the parties, the bankruptcy case, and all but one creditor. 46 On that<br />

basis, it was inclined to find that the transfer was not extraterritorial; therefore, the<br />

presumption did not apply, leaving section 548 applicable as in any domestic case. 7<br />

However, it was troubled by the presence of one significant contact on the Bermuda<br />

side: the property in question was Bermuda real estate. 4s For obvious and sensible<br />

39. French, 440 F.3d at 149.<br />

40. Equal Employment Opportunity Comm. v. Arabian American Oil Co., 499 U.S. 244, 248, 111<br />

S.Ct. 1227, 1230, 113 L.Ed.2d 274 (1991) ("Aramco") (quoting Foley Bros., Inc. v. Filardo, 336 U.S. 281,<br />

285, 69 S.Ct. 575, 577-78, 93 L.Ed. 680 (1949)). See generally William S. Dodge, Understanding the<br />

Presumption Against Extraterritoriality, 16 BERKELEY J. INT'L L. 85 (1998).<br />

41. But see Hartford Fire Ins. Co. v. California, 509 U.S. 764, 813 (1993); Smith v. United <strong>State</strong>s, 507<br />

U.S. 197 (1993). See generally David M. Green & Walter Benzija, Spanning the Globe: The Intended<br />

Extraterritorial Reach of the Bankruptcy Code, 10 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 85 (2002).<br />

42. See Dodge, supra note 40, at 95-98.<br />

43. In re Interbulk, 240 B.R. 195, 199 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 1999); In re Florsheim Group, Inc., 336 BR.<br />

126 (Bankr. N.D. Ill. 2005) (in preference action contact counting showed center of gravity in United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

where title passed in the United <strong>State</strong>s and payment made from the United <strong>State</strong>s).<br />

44. In re French, 440 F.3d 145, 151-2 (4th Cir. 2006), cert. denied, 127 S. Ct. 72 (2006).<br />

45. WEINTRAUB, supra note 21, § 1.5; McDOUGAL, supra note 21, § 84. See also In Regus Business<br />

Centre Corp., 301 B.R. 122 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 2003).<br />

46. French, 440 F.3d at 150.<br />

47. Id.<br />

48. Id.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 906 2006-2007


2007<br />

AVOIDANCE OF PRE-BANKRUPTCY TRANSACTIONS<br />

reasons, all choice-of-law rules recognize that real estate is almost always governed<br />

by the law of its location. 9 Yet it is also clear that this rule is not absolute. So, for<br />

example, decisions in domestic relations cases have applied the law of the domicile<br />

of the marriage to questions of ownership of real estate as between husband and<br />

wife." Nonetheless, the court was sufficiently concerned about the countervailing<br />

weight of the real estate rule that it turned to the second argument for finding the<br />

presumption inapplicable: the wording and policy of the Bankruptcy Code."<br />

2. Congressional Intent<br />

The discussion of the Code was largely a restatement of the contacts counting<br />

and weighing discussion that preceded it. That part of the court's discussion was of<br />

limited analytical value. The interpretive ground for avoiding the presumption is<br />

not, after all, about choosing one law or the other; instead, it rests on whether the<br />

Congress intended this United <strong>State</strong>s law to apply under these circumstances. If not,<br />

no choice of law is presented. The analysis should turn on whether a Congress<br />

anxious to undo fraudulent conveyances would want to permit them whenever the<br />

property involved was foreign real estate, but the court did not focus on that specific<br />

question.<br />

On the other hand, a close examination of the statutory language was more<br />

fruitful. The court worked through section 541(a)(1) of the Bankruptcy Code, which<br />

defines property of the bankrupt estate in the broadest possible terms, 52 and section<br />

1334 of Title 28 of the United <strong>State</strong>s Code, which gives the bankruptcy courts<br />

jurisdiction of "all property, wherever located, of the debtor." 53 The awkwardness of<br />

that phrase reflects the fact that "wherever located" was added to the bankruptcy<br />

law precisely to make it clear that the United <strong>State</strong>s bankruptcy courts were to claim<br />

worldwide jurisdiction of the debtor's property, 4 without distinction between real<br />

and personal property (immovables and movables). The court reasonably concluded<br />

that the combination of these two provisions demonstrated Congress' intent to<br />

include the debtor's worldwide property in the estate, and therefore, that they likely<br />

intended to include foreign property transferred before bankruptcy within the reach<br />

of the bankruptcy avoidance powers. 55 That conclusion was buttressed by a similar<br />

analysis by the Fifth Circuit Court of Appeals, albeit in a different context. 6<br />

Oddly enough, neither the Fourth nor the Fifth Circuits cited or discussed<br />

section 541(a)(3) of the Bankruptcy Code which explicitly includes in the property of<br />

49. WEINTRAUB, supra note 21, § 8.2; MCDOUGAL, supra note 21, § 153.<br />

50. See WEINTRAUB, supra note 21, § 8.14.<br />

51. But see In re Florsheim Group, Inc., 336 B.R. 126 ((Bankr. N.D. Ill. 2005) (will not reach the<br />

presumption issue if center of gravity of transfer in United <strong>State</strong>s).<br />

52. 11 U.S.C. § 541(a)(1) (2006).<br />

53. 28 U.S.C. § 1334(e)(1) (2006).<br />

54. See, e.g., In re Globo Comunicacoes E Participacoes S.A. (Globopar), 317 B.R. 235, 250-51 (2004);<br />

see generally, Pub. L. No. 95-598, § 541, 92 Stat. 2594 (1978); K. Nadelman, Revision-of Conflicts Provisions<br />

in the American Bankruptcy Act, 1 INTL COMP. L.Q. 484, at 484-86 (1952) [hereinafter Nadelman,<br />

Revision]; K. Nadelman, The National Bankruptcy Act and the Conflict of <strong>Law</strong>s, 59 HARV. L. REV. 1025<br />

(1946) (discussing the uncertainty that existed before the Bankruptcy Act of 1952 regarding whether<br />

property located abroad was part of the bankruptcy estate under American law).<br />

55. In re French, 440 F.3d 145 (4th Cir. 2006), cert. denied, 127 S. Ct. 72 (2006).<br />

56. Cullen Ctr. Bank & Trust v. Hensley (In re Criswell), 102 F.3d 1411, 1417 (5th Cir.1997).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 907 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:899<br />

the estate all property that the trustee in bankruptcy recovers under the avoiding<br />

powers. That provision strongly suggests that Congress intended the reach of those<br />

powers to be co-extensive with the broad, global embrace of its definition of estate<br />

property, although the bankruptcy court in Midland disagreed."<br />

3. Comity<br />

Having determined that section 548 did apply to the transfer of the Bermuda<br />

property, the French court then turned to the defendants' argument that "comity"<br />

required the court to defer to Bermuda law. 8 The court's rejection of the argument<br />

involved going back through the same contact-counting and weighing it had done<br />

twice before. 59<br />

This sort of unhelpful comity analysis arises from a confusion of the roles of the<br />

comity doctrine and choice-of-law rules. A full treatment of that subject would be<br />

another article, but a brief discussion is warranted. Generally, comity is a doctrine of<br />

deferral to the actions of a foreign court while choice-of-law rules govern deferral to<br />

the laws of a foreign state. The confusion between deferring to judicial actions and<br />

deferring to statutes arose at the start in the classic formulation in Hilton v. Guyot.,o<br />

In that case, the United <strong>State</strong>s Supreme Court defined comity broadly:<br />

"Comity," in the legal sense, is neither a matter of absolute obligation, on<br />

the one hand, nor of mere courtesy and good will, upon the other. But it is<br />

the recognition which one nation allows within its territory to the<br />

legislative, executive, or judicial acts of another nation, having due regard<br />

both to international duty and convenience, and to the rights of its own<br />

citizens, or of other persons who are under the protection of its laws.<br />

Notwithstanding the formulation in Hilton, comity has been used primarily in<br />

the context of enforcement of judgments-the issue presented in Hilton-or other<br />

situations, like parallel litigation, in which the United <strong>State</strong>s courts have decided to<br />

defer to the actions of foreign courts. 62 That application is far preferable to using<br />

comity as a choice-of-law rule, because the comity doctrine has both the virtues and<br />

the deficiencies of a highly flexible, case-by-case doctrine. That flexibility is just<br />

what is needed for deference to foreign courts, while choice-of-law rules should<br />

strive for some level of generality and predictability. 63<br />

57. In re Midland Euro Exch., 347 B.R. 708, 720 (Bankr. C.D. Cal. 2006).<br />

58. French, 440 F.3d at 152.<br />

59. Id. at 153-54.<br />

60. Hilton v. Guyot, 159 U.S. 113,141 (1895).<br />

61. Id. at 163-64 (emphasis added).<br />

62. See generally Steven R. Swanson, The Vexatiousness of a Vexation Rule: International Comity and<br />

Antitrust Injunctions, 30 G.W. INT'L L. & ECON. 1 (1996); Louise Ellen Tietz, Both Sides of the Coin: A<br />

Decade of Parallel Proceedings and Enforcement of Foreign Judgments in Transnational Litigation, 10<br />

ROGER WILLIAMS U. L. REV. 1, at 9-10 (2004); Joel R. Paul, Comity in International <strong>Law</strong>, 32 HARV. INT'L<br />

L. J. 1, at 2 (1991); Molly Warner Lien, The Cooperative and Integrative Models of Judicial Comity: Two<br />

Illustrations Using Transnational Discovery and Beard Scenarios, 50 CATH. U. L. REV. 591 (2001); Michael<br />

D. Ramsey, Escaping International Comity, 83 IOWA L. REV. 893 (1998).<br />

63. See generally, Westbrook, Extraterritoriality, supra note 23, at 75.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 908 2006-2007


2007<br />

AVOIDANCE OF PRE-BANKRUPTCY TRANSACTIONS<br />

The confusion between these two uses of comity is sadly illustrated by the<br />

decision in Maxwell,' 4 still the classic case for choice of avoidance law in the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s courts. 5 In that case, the debtor filed for bankruptcy in both the United<br />

Kingdom and the United <strong>State</strong>s, although de facto the two courts agreed to treat the<br />

United Kingdom as the home-country court.' The upshot of the case was a<br />

worldwide liquidation plan, perhaps the first such plan ever achieved. But an<br />

important legal issue remained unresolved even after the plan was adopted. The<br />

debtor had made substantial payments to its lenders shortly prior to its twin<br />

bankruptcy filings. 67 It was conceded that the payments would be recoverable from<br />

the lenders as avoidable preferences under United <strong>State</strong>s bankruptcy law, but would<br />

not be recoverable under United Kingdom law.' The joint administrators brought<br />

suit to recover the payments under United <strong>State</strong>s law. 69 The bankruptcy court found<br />

that United Kingdom law applied and dismissed the suit.' The district court and<br />

court of appeals affirmed. 7 '<br />

The two lower courts addressed the choice-of-law problem by counting and<br />

weighing contacts to determine if the presumption against extraterritoriality applied<br />

in that case; they found it did and dismissed. 72 The court of appeals seemed to agree<br />

with that approach, but then veered off sharply, resting its affirmance not on the<br />

choice-of-law analysis, but on comity. 73 It was persuaded that the overall good result<br />

in the case, marked by wonderful cooperation between the courts of the two<br />

countries, suggested that the United <strong>State</strong>s should defer to the English courts (and<br />

therefore the English law) as a matter of comity." The result was to aggravate the<br />

confusion between choice of law and comity as a ground for applying foreign law.<br />

There was no similar element in the French case. There was apparently no<br />

proceeding of any kind in Bermuda with which to cooperate or to which to defer.<br />

Thus, the comity discussion in French was simply off the point. The succinct and<br />

well-reasoned opinion in<br />

75<br />

another recent international preference case, Florsheim,<br />

noted that no parallel proceeding was pending in another country, but still discussed<br />

choice-of-law policies a second time in the context of comity. The only effect of this<br />

approach is to create a risk of confusion and error.<br />

64. In re Maxwell Commc'cns Corp., 93 F.3d 1036 (1996). See generally Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook,<br />

The Lessons of Maxwell Communications, 64 FORDHAM L. REV. 2531 (1996); Paul L. Lee, Ancillary<br />

Proceedings Under Section 304 and Proposed Chapter 15 of the Bankruptcy Code, 76 Am. Bankr. L. J. 115,<br />

154-155 (2002); David Costa Levenson, Proposal for Reform of Choice of Avoidance <strong>Law</strong> in the Context of<br />

International Bankruptcies from a U.S. Perspective, 10 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 291, 338-340 (2002).<br />

65. For this confusion, see also In re PSINet Inc., 268 B.R. 358 (2001) (choice-of-law issue discussed as<br />

comity question per Maxwell).<br />

66. The company's headquarters were in England but its largest subsidiaries were in the United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s, so either country could make a claim to be its home country. See Westbrook, Maxwell, supra note<br />

64, at 2541, n.44; Westbrook, Universalism, supra note 6, at 635, n.42.<br />

67. Maxwell, 93 F.3d at 1041.<br />

68. Id. at 1043.<br />

69. Id.<br />

70. Id. at 1044.<br />

71. Id. at 1044, 1054-55.<br />

72. Maxwell, 93 F.3d at 1044.<br />

73. Id. at 1046-50.<br />

74. Id. at 1053.<br />

75. In re Florsheim Group, Inc., 336 B.R. 126, 133 (Bankr. N.D. Il. 2005)<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 909 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:899<br />

IV. MIDLAND<br />

In Midland, 76 the United <strong>State</strong>s debtor ran a Ponzi scheme, which meant that<br />

all its transfers were presumptively made with fraudulent intent under United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

law. The trustee in bankruptcy sought to avoid about $900,000 in transfers to<br />

"SFC," an English company based in London." The transfers were made from the<br />

London account of the debtor's Barbados subsidiary to the New York account of<br />

SFC, although the money ended up back in London. 78 It was agreed that if section<br />

548 of the Bankruptcy Code applied, the transfer was likely avoidable, but that it<br />

was unlikely to be avoidable under English law, which required that the trustee show<br />

that SFC, as transferee, had a guilty state of mind. 79 The analysis of the case was (or<br />

should have been) complicated by the fact that the corporate group was<br />

substantively consolidated in the United <strong>State</strong>s bankruptcy proceeding.,<br />

For some reason the trustee in bankruptcy conceded that avoidance would<br />

require extraterritorial application of section 548. 8 ' Thus, the court had only to<br />

mention in passing the English contacts with the transaction. With the trustee's<br />

concession, the court had no difficulty in determining that the presumption against<br />

extraterritoriality applied, and United <strong>State</strong>s avoidance law could not be used; hence<br />

the transfer was not avoidable.' As the earlier analysis suggested, it seems to me<br />

that the so-called presumption is really code for a choice-of-law analysis, so<br />

conceding that point dictates the conclusion: if the challenged transaction was so<br />

predominantly connected with England that English law should be applied, one can<br />

feel comfortable that Congress would not have intended to apply United <strong>State</strong>s law.<br />

If it were much more connected with the United <strong>State</strong>s, as in French, then the court<br />

should reasonably conclude Congress likely intended to apply United <strong>State</strong>s law.<br />

The merit of that analysis is illustrated by the Midland court's note that the<br />

result was bad policy, vindicating dishonest conduct by debtors. 83 Why ascribe bad<br />

policy to Congress by saying United <strong>State</strong>s avoidance law does not apply? If good<br />

policy would be application of United <strong>State</strong>s law, then it should be applied as<br />

Congress would wish. If, on the other hand, a choice-of-law analysis leads to the<br />

conclusion that English law and policy should apply, then that jurisdiction's<br />

balancing of fraud recovery versus transactional stability should rightly prevail. The<br />

result is good United <strong>State</strong>s policy in that we properly vindicated our ally's<br />

commercial policy in a circumstance where it had more at stake than we did. Thus,<br />

we come back always to choice of law.<br />

From my perspective, the key point is the identity of the debtor. If we ignore<br />

substantive consolidation in this case," and take the debtor's home country ("center<br />

76. See In re Midland Euro Exch., 347 B.R 708, 710-711 (Bankr. C.D.Cal. 2006).<br />

77. Id. at 713-14.<br />

78. Id. at 712-13.<br />

79. Id. at 715.<br />

80. Id. at 711. Substantive consolidation means that the entire group of companies is treated as if it<br />

were one debtor company, with both claims and assets pooled in the bankruptcy. 8A C.J.S. Bankruptcy §<br />

410 (2007). The case presents the complex question of the effect of substantive consolidation on choice of<br />

avoidance law, a problem we put to one side for present purposes.<br />

81. Midland, 347 B.R. at 715.<br />

82. Id. at 720.<br />

83. Id. at 719.<br />

84. Substantive consolidation would amount to a finding that the affiliated corporations were<br />

essentially divisions within the parent corporation, so the corporate form could be ignored. 2-105 COLLIER<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 910 2006-2007


2007<br />

AVOIDANCE OF PRE-BANKRUPTCY TRANSACTIONS<br />

of main interest")" to be in Barbados, I would apply Barbados law. 86 On the other<br />

hand, if we take substantive consolidation as representing a finding that the<br />

subsidiaries in this case were not independent corporations but merely divisions of<br />

the United <strong>State</strong>s debtor, then the transferor was the debtor, its home country was<br />

the United <strong>State</strong>s, and section 548 should apply. There would be no theory under<br />

which English insolvency law would apply in a universalist court on these facts.<br />

V. AL SABAH 7<br />

A Kuwaiti sheikh was found liable in an English court for massive frauds.' He<br />

was a resident of the Bahamas and entered bankruptcy in that jurisdiction. 89 He had<br />

created two trusts that, at the time of bankruptcy, were governed by Cayman Islands<br />

law. His trustee in bankruptcy sought to avoid the creation of these trusts as<br />

"settlements," that is, gratuitous transfers that in the United <strong>State</strong>s would be<br />

attacked as fraudulent conveyances. 9 " Bahamian law provided for avoidance of such<br />

settlements, but only if they were created by traders. 91 Being reluctant to litigate the<br />

question of the debtor's status as a "trader," the trustee wanted to use Cayman<br />

avoidance law which applied whether the debtor was a trader or not. 92 The<br />

Bahamian court in the "main proceeding" 93 duly requested that the Cayman court<br />

permit the trustee to use the Cayman avoiding power to avoid the settlements. The<br />

Cayman court agreed to apply Cayman law. 94 The case was then appealed to the<br />

Privy Council, which affirmed the application of Cayman law. 9 "<br />

Most of the opinion was devoted to a close analysis of statutory provisions<br />

which need not detain us. The ultimate question was whether a particular provision<br />

was applicable in Cayman bankruptcy law and whether it operated in substance like<br />

section 426 of the British Insolvency Act, giving a court broad authority to apply<br />

local bankruptcy law in favor of a foreign trustee in bankruptcy as if it were being<br />

ON BANKRUPTCY 105.09 (15th ed. rev.). That finding would negate any finding of that the debtor's center<br />

of main interest was in Barbados. See generally In re Tri-Continental, 349 B.R. 627 (Bankr. E.D. Cal.).<br />

85. The phrase identifies the country where pends a "main" or primary bankruptcy proceeding under<br />

the Model <strong>Law</strong> on Cross-Border Insolvency, the EU Regulation, and the Code. United Nations<br />

Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong> (UNCITRAL), Model <strong>Law</strong> on Cross-Border Insolvency, art. 17,<br />

§ (2)(a), G.A. Res. 52/158, Annex, art. 10, U.N. Doc. A/RES/52/158 (Jan. 30, 1998); Commission<br />

Regulation 1346/2000, supra note 25, art. 3.1; 11 U.S.C. 1502 (2006).<br />

86. I have not researched Barbados law on this point. It is likely to be, although not necessarily,<br />

similar to English law.<br />

87. Al Sabah v. Grupo Torras S.A. [2005] UKPC 1, [2005] 2 W.L.R. 904.<br />

88. Al Sabah v. Grupo Torras S.A., [2000] Court of Appeal (Civil Division), available at<br />

http://www.ucc.ie/law/restitution/archive/englcases/al-sabah.htm [2000].<br />

89. Al Sabah v. Grupo Torras S.A. [2005] UKPC 1, [2005] 2 W.L.R. 904., at 907. It is not clear when<br />

the debtor became a Bahamian resident and I ignore that point for purposes of this discussion, interesting<br />

as it is.<br />

90. There might have been other grounds for attack, but they are not addressed here.<br />

91. Al Sabah v. Grupo Torras S.A. [2005] UKPC 1, [200512 W.L.R. 904, at 908.<br />

92. Id.<br />

93. See United Nations Commission on International Trade <strong>Law</strong> (UNCITRAL), Model <strong>Law</strong> on<br />

Cross-Border Insolvency, art. 17, § (2)(a), G.A. Res. 52/158, Annex, art. 10, U.N. Doc. A/RES/52/158 (Jan.<br />

30, 1998).<br />

94. Al Sabah v. Grupo Torras S.A. [2005] UKPC 1, [2005] 2 W.L.R. 904, at 908-09.<br />

95. Id. at 922.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 911 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:899<br />

applied in a local bankruptcy proceeding. 96<br />

Thus, it permitted the Bahamian trustee<br />

to appear in the Cayman court and invoke the relevant Cayman avoidance power.<br />

The statutory framework necessarily focused the Privy Council's attention on<br />

questions of jurisdiction and forum rather than choice of law as such, although the<br />

effect of the decision was to apply a Cayman avoiding power to obtain a recovery for<br />

distribution in a Bahamian bankruptcy.<br />

The choice-of-law question was not an important part of the result. Lord<br />

Walker's judgment concluded with a brief reference to the admonition in section<br />

426(5) that the "requested" (Cayman) court take into consideration private<br />

international law in deciding whether to grant the foreign trustee the use of local<br />

avoidance powers, but the reference was passing and in the context of an exercise of<br />

discretion in choice of forum. 97 Thus the choice-of-law result was incidental to those<br />

other elements. 9 "<br />

The result of the statutory structure was the merging of choice of forum with<br />

choice of law and a lack of a place for analysis of the policies at stake in the latter<br />

choice. 99 Of course, I would argue that Bahamian law should have been applied, and<br />

thus the trusts would not be avoidable. 0 0 My argument would rest on the disconnect<br />

between the Cayman avoidance policy and the Bahamian priority and distribution<br />

policy. The priority rules in the two jurisdictions might differ in ways important in<br />

this case, just as their avoidance rules do. Bahamian rules might benefit Creditor<br />

Groups A-D, while Cayman rules might distribute the recovery to Groups C-H.<br />

With regard to avoidance of settlements, the legislators for the two jurisdictions<br />

may have come to different conclusions in balancing the risk of fraud on creditors<br />

versus disruption of ordinary expectations. The legislators for the Bahamas might<br />

have thought that persons in business (traders) were more likely to be slippery<br />

rogues, so for their transactions, the risk of fraud outweighed the costs of market<br />

disruption. If they saw nontraders as less likely to engage in such manipulations,<br />

they might conclude the balance swings the other way with them. By contrast, the<br />

legislators for the Cayman Islands may have thought all debtors were inclined to<br />

trickery in evading creditors. In making their decisions, the Bahamas policy maker<br />

may have concluded that benefiting the A-D groups of creditors was not worth a<br />

broad disruption of transactions, while the Cayman Island's policymakers may have<br />

been anxious to protect the vulnerable C-H groups of creditors entitled to priority<br />

under Cayman law. Yet the recovery in Al Sabah might flow to Creditor Groups A<br />

and B, disrupting Cayman transactions for the benefit of creditors whom neither<br />

policymaker thought important enough to justify that disruption.<br />

In Al Sabah, the configuration of rules was such that the law applied was that of<br />

the place of transacting."' In another case, the place of transacting might have the<br />

96. Id. at 918-20.<br />

97. Id. at 923.<br />

98. For the relationship between choice of law and choice of forum, see Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook,<br />

Theory and Pragmatism in Global Insolvencies: Choice of <strong>Law</strong> and Choice of Forum, 65 AM.BANKR.L.J.<br />

457 (1991).<br />

99. Something similar seems to have happened in a 2001 Florida bankruptcy case involving German<br />

and Florida fraudulent conveyance law, although the opinion is too elliptical to be sure of the exact<br />

holding. In re Wachsmuth, 272 B.R. 766 (Bankr. M.D. Fla. 2001).<br />

100. I assume for this purpose that the Bahaman Islands were the debtor's center of main interest, as<br />

the judgment suggests.<br />

101. More precisely, it was the law under which the trusts were created and the law chosen in the<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 912 2006-2007


2007<br />

AVOIDANCE OF PRE-BANKRUPTCY TRANSACTIONS<br />

weaker avoidance rule and might have been chosen for trust creation for just that<br />

reason. Specifically, the next case might involve a Bahamian bankruptcy under<br />

circumstances where the Bahamian avoidance rule was stronger than the avoidance<br />

rule in the Cayman Islands where the trusts were created. Of course, the Bahamian<br />

trustee would not seek help from the Cayman courts in that situation, having the<br />

stronger rule at home. Would the trustee be permitted to apply the stronger<br />

Bahamian rule in this new case? If so, then the rule of law would be that a<br />

transaction will be avoided if it is avoidable under the law of any state with<br />

reasonable contacts to the transaction or the bankruptcy. Such a general rule strikes<br />

me as almost as bad as the rule under the European Insolvency Regulation, which<br />

appears to provide that the transaction is not avoidable unless it would be avoidable<br />

under both relevant laws." 2 VI. ONE STEP FARTHER<br />

Two special situations concerning the role of nonbankruptcy law are worthy of<br />

further discussion, even though they did not arise in any of these cases. In one<br />

situation, the nonbankruptcy law represents a strong local policy squarely<br />

inconsistent with the home-country bankruptcy policy, creating a "true" conflict. In<br />

the second, the nonbankruptcy law is itself an avoidance law, but one that can be<br />

applied outside of a bankruptcy proceeding.<br />

A. Conflict Between Avoidance <strong>Law</strong> and Other <strong>Law</strong> Governing the Challenged<br />

Transaction<br />

There was no indication in French that Bermuda real estate law had any special<br />

policy against avoidance of a fraudulent conveyance as against a duly recorded deed.<br />

Indeed, it appeared that Bermuda would avoid such a conveyance if made with<br />

actual intent to defraud, so any imposition on Bermuda nonbankruptcy law and<br />

policy by the avoidance of the transfer in French would seem relatively minor. It is<br />

instructive, however, to consider what might have happened had the case presented<br />

a substantial conflict of policies between Bermuda real estate law and United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

bankruptcy law.<br />

Suppose that Bermuda had a strong rule that record title for real estate was<br />

controlling: no attack by way of fraudulent conveyance or constructive trust or other<br />

similar action could undo the effect of a recorded deed. Bermuda might have<br />

adopted such a rule because much of its property is owned by people in other<br />

countries, and it might deplore having many foreign avoidance laws, unknown to its<br />

judges and real estate experts, threaten the integrity of its real estate recordation<br />

system. Thus it might adopt a nondiscriminatory rule that no avoidance power,<br />

domestic or foreign, can undo or contravene a deed. Under those circumstances,<br />

should a. United <strong>State</strong>s court on the facts in French avoid the transfer? If it did,<br />

would its judgment be enforceable?<br />

instruments creating the trusts.<br />

102. Commission Regulation 1346/2000, supra note 25.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 913 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:899<br />

This circumstance would present what the modern choice-of-law literature calls<br />

a "true" conflict.' 3 The interests of the two countries are squarely contrary. The<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s has a substantial interest in protecting the American creditors of this<br />

American debtor from this fraudulent conveyance. 104 Yet we have supposed that<br />

Bermuda might also have a powerful and defensible policy reason for its rule. When<br />

such a conflict is presented, it is most difficult to develop a principled basis for its<br />

resolution. 0 5<br />

The universality of bankruptcy should be the trumping principle, a view that<br />

appears to have been shared by the French court." 6 It underlies the general rule I<br />

have suggested, that the avoidance law of the home country should generally be the<br />

law applied. Where the policies of the two jurisdictions are in equipoise, it would<br />

seem a strong ground for tipping the balance in favor of the home-country rule.<br />

However, we must also consider the enforceability of the avoidance judgment<br />

in French. It is well-settled that courts do not ordinarily enter judgments they know<br />

will be unenforceable. 7 In our hypothetical situation, it seems likely that the<br />

Bermuda court would refuse to enforce a United <strong>State</strong>s court order transferring the<br />

deed to the United <strong>State</strong>s trustee in bankruptcy. However, it is quite possible that<br />

the United <strong>State</strong>s court could achieve its desired result without the intervention of<br />

the Bermuda court. The United <strong>State</strong>s court could order the United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

defendants, the record owners of the Bermuda property, to transfer the deed<br />

themselves. They would presumably be within the personal jurisdiction of the<br />

United <strong>State</strong>s court and subject to contempt sanctions if they failed to comply. This<br />

remedy has been used in Europe in similar cases.'<br />

B. Nonbankruptcy Avoidance <strong>Law</strong><br />

Many jurisdictions have avoidance laws that may be used without depending<br />

upon the existence of a bankruptcy proceeding. 9 These nonbankruptcy avoidance<br />

laws require a somewhat different analysis. These laws are intended for the benefit<br />

of a particular creditor rather than being part of collective enforcement in<br />

bankruptcy. The key question there is whether a trustee in bankruptcy is authorized<br />

103. See generally CURRIE, supra note 22; Patrick Borchers, The Choice-of-<strong>Law</strong> Revolution: An<br />

Empirical Study. 49 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 357, 361 (1992).<br />

104. Note that it was a concealed conveyance, not recorded until almost twenty years after it was<br />

made. We do not know if the French couple carried it on their financial statements or not.<br />

105. WEINTRAUB, supra note 21, §§ 3.1, 3.6; MCDOUGAL, supra note 21, § 85. One could argue that<br />

there is no true conflict on the particular facts presented, because there was only one Bermuda creditor of<br />

the debtor and it would actually benefit from avoidance. Conversely, it appears there were no Bermuda<br />

creditors of the children/transferees who would have been prejudiced by the re-transfer of the property to<br />

the debtor's trustee in bankruptcy. On the other hand, the hypothetical Bermuda rule rests on a policy<br />

relating to real estate deeds generally and that hypothetical policy would have been weakened by the result<br />

in French, so it seems to me to be a real conflict.<br />

106. In re French, 440 F.3d 145, 152 (4th Cir. 2006), cert. denied, 127 S. Ct. 72 (2006).<br />

107. See generally DOUGLAS LAYCOCK, MODERN AMERICAN REMEDIES 855-72 (3d ed. 2002)<br />

108. See X v. Schenkius (Receiver For Y), Court of Appeal of 'S-Hertogenbosch, 6 July 1993 KG<br />

1993, 406; NIPR 1993 No. 469; NJ 1994, 250 reported in 42 NETH. INT'L L. REV. 121 (1995), reprinted in<br />

edited version, Elizabeth Warren & Jay <strong>Law</strong>rence Westbrook, THE LAW OF DEBTORS AND CREDITORS<br />

845 (2005).<br />

109. J.H. DALHUISEN, DALHUISEN ON INTERNATIONAL INSOLVENCY AND BANKRUPTCY, Vol 1,<br />

Part 11, § 2..05 (1986).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 914 2006-2007


2007<br />

AVOIDANCE OF PRE-BANKRUPTCY TRANSACTIONS<br />

to use such a law by both the bankruptcy laws of the home country and the local<br />

avoidance law. In the United <strong>State</strong>s, for example, the trustee in bankruptcy is<br />

authorized to use such statutes enacted under state nonbankruptcy law." 1 Thus in Al<br />

Sabah, if the Cayman Islands settlement-avoidance law was not part of its<br />

bankruptcy law, and if the Cayman courts had interpreted their law to permit its use<br />

by a trustee in bankruptcy, a United <strong>State</strong>s trustee could avoid the settlement under<br />

Cayman law and distribute the proceeds in the United <strong>State</strong>s proceeding without the<br />

policy anomalies I have asserted above. The analysis is different from the earlier<br />

one because the Cayman nonbankruptcy avoidance law would be intended to benefit<br />

any creditor, not to protect the creditors specified in a bankruptcy distribution<br />

scheme. Thus, there may be no policy anomaly in distributing the proceeds to<br />

creditors generally under whatever priority scheme may exist in the home-country.<br />

VII. CONCLUSION<br />

The three cases discussed here present interesting factual settings for thinking<br />

about choice of law for the avoiding powers, although only French really provides a<br />

rule. It adopts the home-country rule, but without a general theory. Midland turns<br />

on a trustee's concession and ignores the effect of substantive consolidation, while Al<br />

Sabah applies a very broad avoidance rule based on a statute that may not have been<br />

drafted with that result in mind. Thus we still await a case that will give us<br />

predictable results.<br />

The power of avoidance actions and the importance of the policies they serve<br />

make it essential that we move toward a more predictable choice-of-law rule for such<br />

actions. As things stand, a creditor or other transferee of a cross-border transfer<br />

faces a risk of action under a law with seemingly little contact with the transaction or<br />

the debtor. It also faces the risk of liability for the transfer in multiple courts. On<br />

the other hand, the lack of effective actions to avoid cross-border transfers, including<br />

enforcement of avoidance judgments in other jurisdictions, offers an opportunity for<br />

parties to maneuver around the avoidance laws of all the interested jurisdictions,<br />

defeating their bankruptcy policy goals.<br />

The home-country rule suggested here is far from perfect and only moderately<br />

predictable. Anything better must await international agreements that are likely to<br />

be a long time coming. In the meantime, this choice-of-law rule will bring some<br />

coherence and a greater possibility of coordination to multinational insolvencies. It<br />

is a pragmatic goal and an achievable one.<br />

110. 4 ALAN N. RESNICK ET AL, COLLIER ON BANKRUPTCY, paras. 502.03(2)(a), 502.03(2)(b)(ii).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 915 2006-2007


HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 916 2006-2007


The Disappearing Divide Between Property<br />

and Obligation: The Impact of Aligning Legal<br />

Analysis and Commercial Expectation<br />

SARAH WORTHINGTON*<br />

SUMMARY<br />

1. EXPANDING THE NOTION OF PROPERTY: TURNING OBLIGATION INTO<br />

P R O PE R TY ............................................................................................................ 919<br />

II. ATTRIBUTES SAID TO DISTINGUISH PROPERTY FROM OBLIGATION ........... 923<br />

A . Property Term inology ................................................................................. 924<br />

B. The Am bit of Property Rights .................................................................... 924<br />

C. Property Rights May Take Only a Limited Number of Forms- The<br />

N um erus C lausus Principle ........................................................................ 925<br />

D. "Excludability". Property Rights are "Good Against the World ......... 927<br />

E . P roperty is A ssignable ................................................................................ 927<br />

F. Property is Accorded Superior Legal Protection ..................................... 928<br />

G. Property Carries an Entitlement to Proceeds ............................................ 929<br />

H. Property Rights Run with the "Asset"....................................................... 932<br />

L Property Rights Attract Insolvency Protection ......................................... 936<br />

III.<br />

Is DISAPPEARANCE OF THE DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND<br />

O BLIGATION SIGNIFICANT? ............................................................................... 939<br />

"There is nothing which so generally strikes the imagination, and engages the<br />

affections of mankind, as the right of property[]"'<br />

The thesis of this article is simple and startling: equity, acceding to persistent<br />

commercial pressure, has effectively eliminated the divide between property and<br />

obligation, or between property rights and personal rights. Equity has achieved this<br />

This material was first published in Equity in Commercial <strong>Law</strong> (Simone Degeling & James Edelman<br />

eds., Thomson <strong>Law</strong>book Co. 2005), and is republished with very minor amendments here with the<br />

permission of the publishers and editors.<br />

1. WILLIAM BLACKSTONE, 2 COMMENTARIES *2.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 917 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:917<br />

in partnership with the common law and statute, but equity initiated the process and<br />

played a dramatic and innovative developmental role.<br />

This idea that there has been a collapse of boundaries is no mean assertion,<br />

especially given the widely perceived importance of property, and the general<br />

assumption that there is a sharp doctrinal and functional divide between property<br />

and obligation. Most lawyers are familiar with Professor Sir Roy Goode's 1987<br />

article on ownership and obligation. He notes that all legal systems sharply<br />

distinguish "property rights from mere personal rights to the delivery or transfer of<br />

an asset. I own property; I am owed performance of a transfer obligation." 2<br />

Important consequences follow from the distinction, or so we always assume.<br />

<strong>Law</strong>yers are not the only ones to observe the division. Economists, too, are passionate<br />

advocates:'<br />

Property rights . . . are among the most critical social institutions,<br />

providing the basis for resource-use decisions and for the assignment of<br />

wealth and political power. As such, the property regime profoundly<br />

influences both economic performance and income distribution in all<br />

economies. Property rights define the accepted array of resource uses,<br />

determine who has decision-making authority, and describe who will<br />

receive the associated rewards and costs of those decisions. Accordingly,<br />

the prevailing system of property rights establishes incentives and time<br />

horizons for investment in physical and human capital, production, and<br />

exchange. Cross-country differences in property rights result in important<br />

differences in economic development and growth .... The property-rights<br />

structure is also critical for the environment and natural resource use...<br />

[and] for establishing and protecting individual social and political rights<br />

within a society. 4<br />

All this warms the hearts of property lawyers. But doubts soon surface. Fifteen<br />

pages later, this same economist notes that "[i]t is useful to view property rights as<br />

contractual outcomes negotiated by parties . . . ."' And Goode, still focusing on the<br />

divide between "owe" and "own," observes a mere five pages into his analysis that<br />

"most obligations owed by B to A to transfer an asset to A are proprietary in nature<br />

rather than merely personal .... ,6 He puts this down to equitable developments.<br />

The difficulties are equally clear to many undergraduates. The typical common<br />

law classification scheme suggests that property is divided into real and personal<br />

property; personal property is, in turn, divided into choses in possession and choses<br />

in action (tangible and intangible property respectively). 7 And then comes the rub.<br />

2. Royston M. Goode, Ownership and Obligation in Commercial Transactions, 103 LAW Q. REV. 433,<br />

433 (1987).<br />

3. Gary D. Libecap, A Transactions-Cost Approach to the Analysis of Property Rights, in THE<br />

ECONOMICS OF CONTRACTS: THEORIES AND APPLICATIONS 140, 140 (Eric Brousseau & Jean Michel<br />

Glachant eds., 2002).<br />

4. Id. (citation omitted).<br />

5. Id. at 155.<br />

6. Goode, supra note 2, at 438 (emphasis added).<br />

7. It is possible to make the scheme more specific by dividing personal property first into chattels real<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 918 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE DISAPPEARING DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND OBLIGATION<br />

Not all choses in action are property: put more starkly, not all obligations are<br />

property. Those "choses" that are not property, or "property rights," are merely<br />

personal rights, or personal obligations. The boundary is never defined. Indeed, it is<br />

often described as subject to revision according to social and political norms.<br />

Lack of a definitive boundary does nothing to diminish academic vigour in<br />

asserting the importance of the divide. This is not a matter of pure semantics or<br />

irrelevant jurisprudence. The distinction is critical for the very practical reason that<br />

property rights appear better protected than personal rights. Criminal law, tort law,<br />

and public/constitutional law may all afford property rights additional protection,<br />

but the starkest illustrations of the benefits of property rights are seen as insolvency<br />

protection, and as the opportunity to recover windfall gains (or unauthorised profits)<br />

when property rights have been misused. These special protective rights are not<br />

unqualified, but the general perception is that they operate to protect property<br />

rights, not personal rights.<br />

It contradicts this perception to suggest that the supposed divide between<br />

property and obligation (and especially between proprietary and non-proprietary<br />

intangibles) is no longer sustainable. In supporting this claim, this chapter proceeds<br />

in two parts. The first part considers the historical development of a dramatically<br />

expanded notion of property. It shows how obligations, or personal rights, have<br />

been increasingly treated as property. The second and longer part demonstrates<br />

how each of the traditional tests commonly regarded as useful in distinguishing<br />

between property and obligation is disintegrating. Attributes once thought to be<br />

specific to "property" are increasingly being accorded to all manner of rights. In<br />

sum, these two parts suggest that not only is the class of property rights expanding,<br />

but that rights that continue to be labeled as "personal" are receiving "proprietary"<br />

protection. In short, the doctrinal and functional divide between property and<br />

obligation is disappearing.<br />

I. EXPANDING THE NOTION OF PROPERTY: TURNING OBLIGATION<br />

INTO PROPERTY<br />

The goal in this section is simply to show that, over time, certain types of once<br />

purely personal obligations have come to be treated as property. The transition has<br />

been largely the result of equity's incursions, although common law and statutory<br />

developments have supported and reinforced the change. The assertion is not<br />

controversial, and the detail needs only to be summarised here. 8 Of course, the<br />

assertion depends on the definition of property. This issue is revisited in the next<br />

section, where some of the most commonly accepted divisions between property and<br />

obligation are examined. For the moment, it is enough to adopt the widely accepted<br />

notion that property is "usable wealth." From amongst a long list of rights of<br />

(leases) and chattels personal (other), and then dividing the latter into choses in possession and choses in<br />

action. Choses in action can then be further subdivided into documentary intangibles and pure intangibles,<br />

but neither of these complications affects the point being made.<br />

8. For further detail, see SARAH WORTHINGTON, EQUITY 51-86 (2003) [hereinafter WORTHINGTON,<br />

EQUITY] (arguing that equity has dramatically expanded the notion of property, not that there is no longer<br />

a division between proprietary and personal rights). See also SARAH WORTHINGTON, PERSONAL<br />

PROPERTY LAW: TEXT AND MATERIALS chs.1, 8 (2000) [hereinafter WORTHINGTON, PERSONAL<br />

PROPERTY LAW] (providing a more general discussion).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 919 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:917<br />

enjoyment typically associated with ownership or other proprietary interests, 9 the<br />

choice is made that the truly essential features of property rights are that rightholders<br />

can transfer their rights, and can exclude third parties from interfering with<br />

their rights. These twin attributes of "transferability" and "excludability"<br />

characterise property rights." 0 Put another way, those with property rights can<br />

control allocation and access.<br />

The early common law approach was to accord proprietary status to real<br />

property (land) and to tangible personal property (goods), but not to intangible<br />

property. Intangible property was not assignable; it was not usable wealth. This<br />

boundary between property and obligation accords with the (now crude) view of<br />

property as a "thing." Tangible. "things" were accorded proprietary advantages and<br />

proprietary protection; intangible "things" were characterised as personal rights<br />

against specific parties, and were not regarded as proprietary.<br />

Equity completely overturned this state of affairs. It dramatically expanded the<br />

category of "property," or proprietary rights, by acting on two fronts. The story is<br />

well known." First, it permitted the assignment of "personal obligations" that were<br />

unassignable at common law. Debts, shares, and other contractual claims thus<br />

became usable wealth. The possibility was further extended to include rights to<br />

future benefits: claims to future dividends, interest payments, royalties and such<br />

could all be sold immediately for value, in advance of entitlement to the underlying<br />

payment. 2 In this way, future benefits could be capitalised immediately and put to<br />

their most efficient use by those agreeing to the exchange.<br />

Sceptics might suggest that this expansion is too limited to contribute to the<br />

agenda suggested here. It permits the assignment of the benefits of personal<br />

contracts; the burdens remain with the original obligor. To take the simplest of<br />

examples, a creditor can assign the benefit of the debt owed to her, but the debtor<br />

cannot assign his obligation to pay his creditor unless, of course, his creditor consents<br />

to substitute performance from the transferee. 3 However, this rather limited form<br />

of assignment of benefits, not burdens, accords with the predominant commercial<br />

pressure to convert these contractual rights into "usable wealth." It is the benefits,<br />

not the burdens, that the parties are keen to assign, so as to capitalise their value.<br />

Indeed, precisely analogous rules apply to transfers of tangible property, where it is<br />

exceedingly difficult (although not impossible) to ensure that positive burdens run<br />

with the property.' Buyer One may agree with his Seller that the fire breaks will be<br />

cleared annually on his newly acquired farm, or that an artistic object will be<br />

displayed only in certain ways. If the farm or the artwork is transferred to a new<br />

buyer, Seller can rarely insist that Buyer Two comply with the same restrictions,<br />

9. See Anthony M. Honor6, Ownership, in OXFORD ESSAYS IN JURISPRUDENCE 107 (A.G. Guest ed.,<br />

1961).<br />

10. See Kevin Gray, Property in Thin Air, 50 CAMBRIDGE L.J. 252, 301-02 (1991).<br />

11. See WORTHINGTON, EQUITY, supra note 8, 51-86 (explaining that all of these new rights are<br />

uncontroversially regarded as assignable, and also as attracting some powers to exclude third parties).<br />

12. It is important to take care, of course, not to contract to transfer the money to be received in the<br />

future, but rather to transfer the existing right to the future income stream. See Norman v. Fed. Comm'r of<br />

Taxation (1963) 109 C.L.R. 9 (Austl.).<br />

13. The three-way agreement between debtor, creditor, and transferee is typically achieved by<br />

novation of the original debtor/creditor contract.<br />

14. See Bernard Rudden, Economic Theory v. Property <strong>Law</strong>: The Numerus Clausus Problem, in<br />

OXFORD ESSAYS IN JURISPRUDENCE 239, 241-43 (John Eekelaar & John Bell eds., Third Series,<br />

Clarendon Press, 1987).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 920 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE DISAPPEARING DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND OBLIGATION<br />

unless the two have contracted directly with each other to that effect. In some<br />

circumstances, this inability to ensure that positive burdens run with tangible and<br />

intangible assets can reduce the economic value of the assets in question. The next<br />

section makes it clear that all three branches of the law-equity, common law, and<br />

statute-have made advances to improve matters on this front, while balancing the<br />

need to protect Buyer Two from unexpected burdens. But the difficulties across the<br />

board only serve to reinforce the similarities in treating tangible and intangible assets<br />

as "property."<br />

As ' well as expanding the class of rights that were assignable, equity's second<br />

strategy was simply to create completely new forms of property. It did this by<br />

permitting novel divisions of certain "bundles of rights" (property rights) that the<br />

common law had previously regarded as indivisible, and then, over time, reclassifying<br />

these novel bundles as "property" rather than "obligation."<br />

To understand this second strategy, it is necessary to go back a step. Dividing<br />

property between different parties is commercially attractive. At common law, such<br />

divisions are possible. Tangible things (land and goods) can be co-owned, with<br />

several owners sharing the sum total of the relevant property rights. In the simplest<br />

case, a division of rights between co-owners can give them interests that are<br />

qualitatively the same, even if quantitatively different. Co-ownership of a horse, for<br />

example, might divide ownership rights : 'A: 4. More sophisticated strategies allow<br />

different parties to have different types of interests in the same asset, not merely<br />

different shares of the interest. With tangible personal property, the common law<br />

allowed the parties to split ownership and possession between different parties.<br />

With land, the common law went even further and allowed different parties to have<br />

sequential ownership interests along a time-line, via the doctrine of estates. In this<br />

way, the practical and commercial benefits of divided property ownership were<br />

recognised and accommodated by the common law. Although these common law<br />

options for divided ownership appear limited (especially for tangible personal<br />

property), their innovative potential should not be underestimated. For example,<br />

the simple division of ownership and possession of goods permits different forms of<br />

leases (with all manner of associated covenants), hire-purchase agreements, pledges,<br />

contractual liens, retention of title sales, bailments, and more.<br />

Equity dramatically expanded upon these rather meagre common law<br />

possibilities for divided interests. It did this through the creation of trusts and<br />

charges. These two structures are often assumed to be equity's greatest legacy to the<br />

law. Their enormous commercial significance goes without saying. These devices<br />

began as contractual arrangements ("personal obligations"), and slowly evolved<br />

until they were unequivocally recognised as delivering new (divided) property<br />

interests in the underlying tangible or intangible assets." The terms "trust" and<br />

"charge" disguise the enormous flexibility permitted within these categories. Taking<br />

each in turn, "trusts" permit the division of interests according to the common law<br />

model (that is, shared and sequential ownership) regardless of the nature of the<br />

underlying asset. But this is just the start. Trusts enable endless innovation and<br />

division, limited only by the imagination of interested commercial parties. Assets<br />

can be subdivided at will, and different types of rights can be parcelled out to<br />

15. See WORTHINGTON, EQUITY, supra note 8. "Asset" is used very loosely as shorthand for bundles<br />

of rights, whether proprietary or personal.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 921 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:917<br />

different parties.' 6 Using the trust, for example, rights associated with company<br />

shares can be divided to give certain parties the voting rights, others the dividend<br />

rights, and still others the rights to bonus issues. Even this does not exhaust the<br />

divided rights that are possible because of the trust. Consider the many formal and<br />

informal arrangements that are now considered to deliver trust structures of divided<br />

ownership. The best known include Quistclose trusts," building retention trusts,'<br />

and constructive trusts arising in response to contracts of sale 9 or, occasionally,<br />

family agreements. 0<br />

"Equitable charges" are a more recent legal innovation. They evolved in a<br />

similar fashion to trusts, however, and now provide enormous flexibility in enabling<br />

contracting parties to structure security arrangements that accommodate their<br />

individual needs and circumstances. The rapid evolution and growing commercial<br />

significance of equitable charges can be seen clearly in the evolving debates<br />

surrounding the granting of security over after-acquired assets, 2 ' the recognition of<br />

floating charges 22 and automatic crystallisation clauses, 23 and, most recently, the<br />

possibility that a lending bank could take a charge (a "charge back") over the<br />

debtor's account with the same bank. 24 The ability of well-advised creditors to<br />

protect themselves against their debtor's insolvency using such devices quickly led to<br />

parliament providing statutory protection for certain classes of unsecured third<br />

parties, especially against floating charge holders. 25 This, in turn, led to a fresh round<br />

of debates (still on-going) about the accurate characterisation of parties'<br />

arrangements as creating these vulnerable floating charges rather than some other<br />

form of proprietary protection such as a fixed charge, 26 a contractual lien in the<br />

context of construction contracts, 27 or legal ownership or a trust in the context of<br />

retention of title agreements. 8 For our purposes, the outcomes of these debates are<br />

16. See generally Henry Hansmann & Ugo Mattei, The Functions of Trust <strong>Law</strong>: A Comparative Legal<br />

and Economic Analysis, 73 N.Y.U. L. REV. 434 (1998); Sarah Worthington, The Commercial Utility of the<br />

Trust Vehicle, in EXTENDING THE BOUNDARIES OF TRUSTS AND SIMILAR RING-FENCED FUNDS 135,135-<br />

162 (David Hayton ed., 2002).<br />

17. See generally THE QUISTCLOSE TRUST: CRITICAL ESSAYS (William Swadling ed., 2004) (exploring<br />

the foundations of the Quistclose trust and subjecting it to a searching analysis).<br />

18. See Mac-Jordan Construction Ltd. v. Brookmount Erostin Ltd., [1992] B.C.L.C. 350 (Eng. 1991).<br />

19. Other than sales of goods, where the Sale of Goods Act 1979 (Eng.) and its Commonwealth<br />

equivalents provide an even more aggressive default rule, so that legal property is rebuttably presumed to<br />

pass to the buyer at the time of the contract of sale, notwithstanding that delivery and payment of the price<br />

occur at some later stage. See Sale of Goods Act, 1979, 28 & 29 Eliz. 2, c. 54, § 18 (Eng.).<br />

20. See SARAH WORTHINGTON, PROPRIETARY INTERESTS IN COMMERCIAL TRANSACTIONS, 43-70,<br />

187-221 (1996) [hereinafter WORTHINGTON, PROPRIETARY INTERESTS] (listing and discussing the relevant<br />

cases); WORTHINGTON, PERSONAL PROPERTY LAW, supra note 8, chs. 3.9, 4.10-4.14.<br />

21. See Holroyd v. Marshall, [1862] 11 Eng. Rep. 999 (H.L.).<br />

22. See In re Yorkshire Woolcombers Ass'n, [1903] 2 Ch. 284.<br />

23. See In re Brightlife Ltd., [1987] Ch. 200.<br />

24. See In re Bank of Credit & Com. Int'l S.A. (No 8), [1998] A.C. 214.<br />

25. Insolvency Act, 1986, c. 45, §§ 40, 175(2)(b), 176A.<br />

26. In In re Spectrum Plus Ltd., the House of Lords finally affirmed the analysis advanced by the<br />

Author. See In re Spectrum Plus Ltd., [2005] UKHL 41, [2005] 2 A.C. 680 (overruling In re Spectrum Plus<br />

Ltd., [2004] Ch. 337); Sarah Worthington, An "Unsatisfactory Area of the <strong>Law</strong>"-Fixed and Floating<br />

Charges Yet Again, 1 INT'L CORP. RESCUE 175 (2004).<br />

27. See In re Cosslett (Contractors) Ltd., [1998] Ch. 495 (analysis not affected by the subsequent<br />

appeal to the House of Lords, Smith (Administrator of Cosslett (Contractors) Ltd) v. Bridgend County<br />

Borough Council, [2002] 1 A.C. 336).<br />

28. See Borden (U.K.) Ltd. v. Scottish Timber Prods. Ltd., [1981] Ch. 25.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 922 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE DISAPPEARING DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND OBLIGATION<br />

not important in themselves. What is important is that they serve to reinforce,<br />

rather dramatically, the notion that "obligations" between parties often count as<br />

"property" of one sort or another.<br />

To summarise, this section suggests that, over time, equity made two very<br />

significant moves. It treated common law obligations as property, simply by<br />

permitting their assignment and providing some protection for the assignees. It also<br />

treated obligations to divide property rights as being in themselves new forms of<br />

property. Put bluntly, equity converted obligations into property. 9<br />

The previous assertion tests "property' by the twin attributes of assignability<br />

and excludability, but even measured in this simple way, there has been a radical<br />

change in what is assigned to the "obligations" box and what to the "property" box.<br />

In itself, of course, this is not sufficient to establish that the divide between<br />

obligation and property has disappeared. The divide may simply have moved to a<br />

different place. The next section seeks to advance the case for disappearance.<br />

II.<br />

ATTRIBUTES SAID TO DISTINGUISH PROPERTY FROM OBLIGATION<br />

In the previous section it was suggested that the hallmarks of property are<br />

"assignability" and "excludability"; in other words, property rights are assignable,<br />

and they entitle their holders to exclude others from their enjoyment. Neither<br />

characteristic needs to be absolute. Indeed, short reflection suggests that there are<br />

no assets that entitle their holder to absolute rights to enjoy, to transfer, and to<br />

exclude others. The burden of this section is to show that these two attributes, along<br />

with several other attributes commonly regarded as indicative of "property" rather<br />

than "obligation," no longer successfully serve this function. None of the attributes<br />

discussed below provides a criterion for confidently allocating an asset to either the<br />

"property box" or the "obligations box." Whatever may have been true in the past,<br />

it now seems that these attributes are, to varying degrees, apt to describe all manner<br />

of assets; there is no clear distinction between property and obligation. In this sense,<br />

the divide between property and obligation is disappearing.<br />

The discussion proceeds in a fashion that reflects a further oddity in the<br />

orthodox property/obligation divide. Rights are either specifically categorised as<br />

"property," or they are not. If they are not, then they are merely personal-they are<br />

"obligations." From this it follows that all the standard tests focus on the attributes<br />

of "property." Absence of the attributes means the asset is "not property" and so is<br />

merely "obligation." The argument in this part is therefore that these property<br />

attributes no longer provide any defensible means of distinguishing between two<br />

types of assets, one "property" and one "obligation."<br />

29. This might be expected to cause problems on at least two fronts: the types of interests that are<br />

recognised as "proprietary" appear to become infinitely variable as the particular contractual terms differ,<br />

so offending the nunerus clausus rule and its justifications; and third parties may seem to be treated<br />

unfairly in being expected to recognise such a vast spectrum of property rights, and facing liability for<br />

unwittingly infringing them.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 923 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:917<br />

A. Property Terminology<br />

<strong>Law</strong>yers must be careful with language, and clearly, loose language does not<br />

mean that implicit inaccuracies automatically become legal doctrine. Nevertheless,<br />

some usages are instructive. When we talk of a company's property, for example, we<br />

certainly do not mean to refer only to the tangible "things" owned by the firm, as<br />

distinct from all the other rights owed to it by third parties. In the same vein, when<br />

we say that a trust cannot be created unless there is "trust property" held by the<br />

trustee on trust for the beneficiaries, we include within the notion of "trust property"<br />

both tangible "things" owned by the trustee as well as every type of obligation owed<br />

to the trustee for the benefit of the trust. And when either a company or a trustee<br />

becomes insolvent, the assets available for division amongst the creditors include all<br />

the relevant tangible and intangible assets (i.e. the entire pool of property and<br />

obligations). Recent doctrinal and functional discussion of "asset partitioning," 3 or<br />

divided patrimonies (in civil law jurisdictions), involves a similar bundling of<br />

property and obligation. The "asset partitioning" does not discriminate at all<br />

between different assets, or different forms of wealth. With affirmative asset<br />

partitioning, all corporate wealth or trust wealth is partitioned, segregated as a pool<br />

dedicated to service the claims of the corporate or trust creditors rather than the<br />

shareholders' or beneficiaries' creditors; conversely, with defensive asset<br />

partitioning, all the shareholders' or beneficiaries' wealth, in whatever form, is<br />

partitioned, preserved intact against the claims of the corporate or trust creditors. In<br />

short, our common use of language affords no help in distinguishing between<br />

property and obligation. This is so even when we appear to use the distinction<br />

technically, as in requiring identification of trust "property," or an insolvent's<br />

"property."<br />

B. The Ambit of Property Rights<br />

Professor Honor6 described ownership as "the greatest possible interest in a<br />

thing which a mature system of law recognizes."'" Perhaps derived from this, there is<br />

increasing currency given to the notion of property as a bundle of rights which<br />

includes residual incidents operating in favour of the owner once all other claims<br />

have been met. Rights are proprietary if they encompass this broad scope; otherwise<br />

they are personal. Again, however, the approach does not appear to assist in<br />

distinguishing between property and obligation.<br />

This claim is best shown by example, and the clearest modern example comes<br />

from corporate law scholarship. There the notion of residual rights is frequently<br />

used, admittedly, more often by economists rather than by lawyers. The analysis<br />

usually proceeds along the following lines: residual rights indicate ownership; the<br />

shareholders have residual rights to the company's property on insolvency, so the<br />

shareholders own this property; as owners, they have the right to control its use, and<br />

to do so by controlling the board of directors. This is clearly too crude. Either we<br />

have misconceived the meaning of residual rights (perhaps employees and creditors<br />

also have such rights?), or these rights do not invariably suggest property ownership.<br />

30. See generally Henry Hansmann & Reinier Kraakman, The Essential Role of Organizational <strong>Law</strong>,<br />

110 YALE L.J. 387 (2000) (discussing various aspects of asset partitioning).<br />

31. Honor6, supra note 9, at 108.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 924 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE DISAPPEARING DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND OBLIGATION<br />

By contrast, the accepted analysis, at least for lawyers, is that the shareholders<br />

do not own the company's assets: they do not need to, and there are significant<br />

advantages if they do not. Because of express or default rules in their share contract,<br />

however, they have ultimate residual rights to the company's property on its<br />

insolvency. The vulnerability of this residual claim provides the necessary<br />

motivation for shareholders to monitor the corporate managers. Other groups are at<br />

risk of poor corporate management, but their risk is not quite so great (they are<br />

further up the chain), and their coordination costs are much higher, especially if their<br />

interests are diverse. This analysis explains why the monitoring role might<br />

reasonably be left to shareholders. However, it does not provide automatic<br />

justification for shareholder control of corporate management or the managers' need<br />

to run the company exclusively in the shareholders' interests." Some other<br />

justification is needed for that. And, finally, it delivers all this without the need to<br />

differentiate between property and obligation: the consequences follow because the<br />

shareholders, as a group, have uniform residual contract/obligation rights.<br />

So, again, identifying residual rights may indicate "property," but equally it may<br />

indicate "obligation"; it is not a distinguishing attribute.<br />

C. Property Rights May Take Only a Limited Number of Forms-the Numerus<br />

Clausus Principle<br />

It is commonly observed that most legal systems recognise only a limited (and<br />

non-expanding) number of property interests. Personal rights, by contrast, can be<br />

structured in an infinite number of ways to suit the parties' personal needs. This<br />

alleged restriction on the possible forms of property is known as the numerus clausus<br />

(closed number) rule. Civil law jurisdictions certainly have such a rule, and it is<br />

supposedly the reason why trusts do not exist in these jurisdictions. The common<br />

law rule, if there is one, is much more ambivalent. Equity's permitted subdivision of<br />

interests in assets, and the concomitant creation of new forms of property, especially<br />

forms that can be specially tailored by the parties to suit their own personal<br />

requirements, appears to offend the numerus clausus rule. In this respect, at least,<br />

equitable property rights appear much more like personal rights, and it is not at all<br />

evident that the numerus clausus rule places any real restrictions on the<br />

property/obligation divide in common law jurisdictions.<br />

In any event, the rationale for the rule has been shown to be suspect. If the<br />

goal is simply to reduce the number of property options because of some perceived<br />

efficiency in this, then it fails. The desired variety of rights which might operate in<br />

relation to property can usually be achieved by contract in any event, although with<br />

greater effort and therefore greater inefficiency. 33 The principle thus serves as an<br />

ineffective (and inefficient) restraint. Indeed, jurisdictions that did not expand the<br />

variety of their property rights by incremental development have generally sought to<br />

32. See Sarah Worthington, Shares and Shareholders: Property, Power and Entitlement, Part 1, 22<br />

COMPANY LAWYER 258 (2001) (exploring the nature and extent of a shareholder's legal entitlement to<br />

have a company's business conducted so as to maximize shareholder value); Sarah Worthington, Shares<br />

and Shareholders: Property, Power and Entitlement, Part 11, 22 COMPANY LAWYER 307 (2001) (exploring<br />

the nature and extent of a shareholder's legal entitlement to have a company's business conducted so as to<br />

maximize shareholder value).<br />

33. Rudden, supra note 14, at 239.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 925 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:917<br />

do this later, via statute, and to do so in a manner that accords these rights<br />

proprietary status, or at least some measure of protection from interference by third<br />

parties." For example, civil law jurisdictions are increasingly adopting trusts<br />

legislation;" the United <strong>State</strong>s, which did not initially grant judicial recognition to the<br />

floating charge, now achieves the same ends via the United <strong>State</strong>s Uniform<br />

Commercial Code Article 9; and several jurisdictions, including Hong Kong, recently<br />

legislated to ensure the validity of charge backs.<br />

Alternatively, if the reason for the principle is to prevent the multiplication of<br />

sub-interests in assets, so as to ensure that dealings do not become difficult and<br />

inefficient, then it also fails. It controls the types of interests that may be created, but<br />

not the numbers of parties who may hold such (restricted) interests, and it is the<br />

latter that is likely to make dealings inefficient. 36<br />

Finally, if the principle is designed to protect property owners by alerting<br />

strangers to the property rights they must respect, and does so by affording third<br />

parties easy notice 37 or easy verification" of these property packages, then it also<br />

fails. Once we examine the strategies the law employs to protect property owners<br />

(and, indeed, all right owners), it becomes clear that the strategy is not to limit the<br />

number of recognised property rights (adhering to the numerus clausus principle),<br />

but to limit the number of risks to which a stranger can be exposed and which might<br />

count as unauthorised interference with the rights of others." A large degree of<br />

flexibility as between the originating parties, A and B, could be accommodated<br />

without increasing the information costs for C if the broad rules of liability imposed<br />

on C are few and simple. This means that there is no need to adhere to the numerus<br />

clausus principle, as long as a simple philosophy is applied in constructing the<br />

remedial regime. The approaches usually adopted are described later in this essay."<br />

In summary, the numerus clausus characteristic does not enable common<br />

lawyers to differentiate between property and obligation, and in any event the<br />

perceived advantages of the rule appear overrated.<br />

34. For other approaches, see George L. Gretton, Trusts without Equity, 49 INT'L & COMP. L.Q. 599<br />

(2000) (assessing trusts as patrimony).<br />

35. See Hansmann & Mattei, supra note 16, at 458; David Hayton, English Trusts and Their<br />

Commercial Counterparts in Continental Europe, in EXTENDING THE BOUNDARIES OF TRUSTS AND<br />

SIMILAR RING-FENCED FUNDS, supra note 16, at 23.<br />

36. See Henry Hansmann & Reinier Kraakman, Property, Contract, and Verification: The Numerus<br />

Clausus Problem and the Divisibility of Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. 373, 418 (2002).<br />

37. See Thomas W. Merrill & Henry E. Smith, Optimal Standardization in the <strong>Law</strong> of Property: The<br />

Numerus Clausus Principle, 110 YALE L.J. 1, 43 (2000).<br />

38. See Hansmann & Kraakman, supra note 36.<br />

39. See Merrill & Smith, supra note 37, at 25 (taking the view that the numerus clausus principle plays<br />

an important role here).<br />

40. Here a simple example suffices. All the characterisation and recharacterisation problems<br />

associated with floating charges-especially in the context of construction contracts and retention of title<br />

agreements-are at root related to the proper treatment of certain third parties, and to determining<br />

whether they have statutory rights in the underlying asset (since the Insolvency Act 1986 (U.K.) gives<br />

preferred creditors rights against assets subject to floating charges). They are not related to determining<br />

whether the charge agreement between A and B is limited to a known form of property interest.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 926 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE DISAPPEARING DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND OBLIGATION<br />

D. "Excludability": Property Rights are "Good Against the World"<br />

Property rights are commonly described as "rights in rem," "good against the<br />

world" (or at least a section of it), and "multital."' Personal rights, by contrast, are<br />

4 ' 2<br />

described as "rights in personam," only good against the obligee, and "paucital.<br />

This is a formal, but perhaps less informative, assertion of the idea of excludability.<br />

Restated as they are here, two ideas may be unwittingly confused in these<br />

descriptions (or maybe wittingly). First, property rights are still often described as<br />

rights in an asset, not simply rights to an asset (orthodoxy suggests the latter would<br />

be rights in rem, and personal rather than proprietary)." This distinction now lacks<br />

force or accuracy. Equity has ensured that rights to assets are commonly accorded<br />

all the attributes of property rights." The evolution was described earlier in this<br />

article. In truth, this now outdated notion of "rights in rem" replicates the equally<br />

outdated early idea of property as a "thing." The more modern conception of<br />

property is as a "bundle of rights," and, moreover, a bundle of rights exercisable<br />

against people, even if in relation to a thing.<br />

The second theme in this labelling emerges in the multital/paucital distinction:<br />

rights in rem are good against the world; purely personal rights can usually only be<br />

enforced against mutually consenting parties. But this focus is on something other<br />

than our property/obligation divide. Under this classification, all tort claims are in<br />

rem since they bind all the world in relation to trespass, nuisance, negligence, and<br />

such like. "Things" are protected by these general defensive claims, but so too are<br />

personal rights: we now have the tort of inducing a breach of contract, for example,<br />

interfering with obligation, rather than with property. 5 This means that rights may<br />

be classified as in rem, or good against the world, even though we would not usually<br />

think of them as "property" in any real sense, but rather as "obligations" that are<br />

simply and similarly protected by claims that may be advanced against the whole<br />

world.<br />

Once again, the familiar "property attribute" no longer provides a reliable<br />

distinction between property and obligation.<br />

E. Property is Assignable<br />

As noted earlier, it is no longer possible to suggest that "property" is<br />

assignable, but "obligations," or contract rights, are not. The modern rule is that<br />

both are assignable, but both may have specific practical or procedural limitations on<br />

assignment imposed by common law or statute for reasons of public policy. These<br />

limitations do not serve to distinguish "property" from "obligation." Indeed, greater<br />

41. WESLEY NEWCOLMB HOHFELD, FUNDAMENTAL LEGAL CONCEPTIONS As APPLIED IN JUDICIAL<br />

REASONING 111-14 (Walter Wheeler Cook ed., Greenwood Press 1978) (1919).<br />

42. Id. at 69-74.<br />

43. Goode, supra note 2, at 433-34.<br />

44. See id. at 438.<br />

45. See Lumley v. Gye, (1853) 118 E.R. 749; see also Daniel Friedmann, Restitution of Benefits<br />

Obtained Through the Appropriation of Property or the Commission of a Wrong, 80 COLUM. L. REV. 504,<br />

513-29 (1980).<br />

46. See, e.g., Royston M. Goode, Notes of Cases, Inalienable Rights?, 42 MOD. L. REV. 553, 553-57<br />

(1979).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 927 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:917<br />

restrictions apply to the assignment of some forms of tangible property (the clearest<br />

elements in the "property" category) than apply to the assignment of most<br />

"obligations." Consider the restrictions on assignment of certain categories of land,<br />

or certain categories of goods (such as national art treasures, or petrol in periods of<br />

national shortage). Put another way, public policy determines whether a particular<br />

bundle of rights is assignable, and it does this without regard to the<br />

property/obligation divide. And when public policy determines whether it is<br />

appropriate to sell human beings into slavery, cell lines to research laboratories, or<br />

rights to litigate to the highest bidder, it does not first decide whether these rights<br />

are property. It moves immediately to the core controversies. Once again, the<br />

attribute does not serve to define a given right as property rather than obligation.<br />

F. Property is Accorded Superior Legal Protection<br />

We commonly assume that property is better protected by the legal system than<br />

contract, or obligation. This remedial insight was articulated more formally by<br />

Calabresi and Melamed almost thirty years ago. 47 They suggested that property<br />

rights are distinguishable because they are protected through "property rules," not<br />

merely through "liability rules." Put in more familiar language, injunctions and<br />

specific performance are the norm in protecting property rights, rather than mere<br />

payment of compensation. 48 Once again, however, this preferential remedial<br />

approach no longer seems to track any meaningful property/obligation divide.<br />

Take some obvious examples. Rights that we might classify as purely personal<br />

(that is, as "obligations," rather than "property") often seem to be protected by<br />

"property rules." For example, tort claims of all types are typically remedied by<br />

compensation, but also, quite commonly, by positive or negative injunctions. The<br />

difference in remedy does not turn on whether the damage has already been done, 49<br />

nor, any longer, on whether the rights that have been infringed are "proprietary." ' 5 '<br />

Contract rights, too, are enforced using the full panoply of remedies. This remains<br />

true even when the rights infringed appear to be especially "personal," rather than<br />

"proprietary," such as those requiring personal services to be performed by the<br />

defendant for the claimant." Generalising, it seems that "obligations" are<br />

47. Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One<br />

View of the Cathedral, 85 HARv. L. REV. 1089 (1972).<br />

48. Robert Chambers, The Importance of Specific Performance, in EQUITY IN COMMERCIAL LAW<br />

(Simone Degeling & James Edelman eds., 2005) (discussing this issue at length, while also discussing these<br />

two cases: Smelhago v. Paramedevan, (1996) 136 D.L.R. (4th) 1 & Tanwar Enterprises Pty Ltd v. Cauchi,<br />

(2003) 217 C.L.R. 315).<br />

49. Even if the damage is still only threatened, the claimant may be obliged to take compensation for<br />

the likely harm that will be caused, rather than be afforded an injunction. Lord Cairns' Act (Chancery<br />

Amendment Act), 1858, 21 & 22 Vict., c. 27 (U.K.) (now re-enacted in the Supreme Court Act 1981, § 54).<br />

50. Proprietary in the sense that the tort interferes with the claimant's rights, and those rights are<br />

proprietary rather than personal (property rather than contract). At another level, all tort "rights" are<br />

sometimes considered "proprietary," since they can be enforced against all the world-that is they are<br />

rights in rem. See discussion supra Part lI.D.<br />

51. Co-operative Ins. Soc'y Ltd. v. Argyll Stores (Holdings) Ltd., [1998] A.C. 1. But see Lumley v.<br />

Wagner, (1852) 42 Eng. Rep. 687 (where the courts were prepared to order an injunction, but not specific<br />

performance).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 928 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE DISAPPEARING DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND OBLIGATION<br />

sufficiently commonly protected by "property rules" for this form of enhanced legal<br />

protection to be of little use in distinguishing property from obligation. 2<br />

The inability of this remedial attribute to provide a distinguishing test appears<br />

all the more stark when the issues are examined form the property perspective.<br />

Then we notice that our legal system does not necessarily protect some of the most<br />

uncontroversial "property" forms by means of property rules, but prefers, instead, to<br />

limit protection to liability rules. This is the approach taken by the common law in<br />

protecting goods (that is, tangible personal property). These assets are clearly<br />

property, but they are not (or not necessarily) protected by property rules: an owner<br />

whose goods have been converted by another is entitled to compensation rather than<br />

to specific recovery (unless the court exercises its statutory discretion to order the<br />

latter) .53<br />

Generalising, the more accurate analysis seems to be that the special protective<br />

regimes that deliver performance rather than damages (Calabresi and Melamed's<br />

"property rules") are not afforded exclusively to property rights. Rather, they are<br />

afforded to all scarce rights, whether those rights are classified as property or as<br />

obligation. Once again, this aspect of the law's remedial regime does not enable us<br />

to distinguish between property and obligation.<br />

G. Property Carries an Entitlement to Proceeds<br />

Property rights are commonly associated with automatic entitlement to any<br />

proceeds derived from the property. An owner can sell her car and keep the<br />

proceeds; she can hire the car out and the income is hers. The same is equally true<br />

of assets that are more on the margins of property and obligation: owners of shares<br />

or debts may sell these assets and keep the proceeds; 54 and before such sale, they are<br />

entitled to the dividends or interest payments. But the same is also true of rights we<br />

class as pure obligations. Contracts of supply, or service, or hire can all be sold, and<br />

the proceeds belong to the seller; 55 and if these personal rights are not sold, then any<br />

benefits that accrue from them belong to their owner. It seems that all assets carry<br />

with them an entitlement to proceeds, and this is equally true whether the assets are<br />

classed as property or obligation. This is not controversial.<br />

Much more controversial, however, is whether this same entitlement to gains<br />

applies when the gains are made by third parties making unauthorised use of the<br />

rights, rather than made by the right-owner herself. In these circumstances, can the<br />

owner still insist that she is entitled to the benefits derived from her asset? In<br />

making this claim, the owner is asking for a "disgorgement" remedy (or<br />

"restitutionary damages" or "an account of profits"). Does this remedy map the<br />

property/obligation divide?<br />

52. See Lionel Smith, Understanding Specific Performance, in COMPARATIVE REMEDIES FOR<br />

BREACH OF CONTRACT 221, 223 (Nili Cohen & Ewan McKendrick eds., 2005) (coming to a similar<br />

conclusion).<br />

53. Torts (Interference with Goods) Act, 1977, ch. 32 (U.K.).<br />

54. Sometimes the sale is subject to restrictions, or even prohibitions, but this is equally true of<br />

tangible property.<br />

55. Again, the sale may be subject to restrictions, or even prohibitions, but this is no different from<br />

the earlier property examples.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 929 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:917<br />

This is difficult, because there is as yet no firm consensus on the availability of<br />

disgorgement as a remedy. The possibility of such a claim can arise in a variety of<br />

circumstances, and involve a wide range of assets. Depending upon the<br />

circumstances, different analyses are possible, and none has so far attracted<br />

consistent judicial (or academic) following. In an earlier essay, I discussed the<br />

paradigm case of a third party using a £1 coin to purchase what turned out to be the<br />

winning lottery ticket. -6 The lottery winnings represent the "proceeds" from the £1<br />

coin. Must these winnings be paid over to the original owner of the £1 coin? Does it<br />

matter whether the original owner remains the legal (or equitable) owner of the<br />

money throughout (that is, has a property right), or whether she has only a personal<br />

claim for recovery of its value from the third party (in unjust enrichment, for<br />

example)? Does it matter whether the third party was from the start a trustee of the<br />

money, or stole it, or received it completely innocently, perhaps by way of gift?<br />

Contract law and tort law can compensate the original owner for any harm suffered;<br />

the law of unjust enrichment can restore expropriated gains. But these remedies, if<br />

they are available, will rarely deliver much more than £1 (the original asset, perhaps<br />

plus some further amount for loss of use of the money for some period of time). Is<br />

there a rule that will also restore the third party's windfall gains to the claimant?<br />

If it is clear that the original owner has retained a property interest in the asset<br />

despite its transfer to the third party, then (at least in the UK) it is often assumed<br />

that she will be able to recover windfall gains from interfering third parties. A 1997<br />

Court of Appeal decision suggests this conclusion follows naturally from the nature<br />

of property rights themselves: owners are entitled to the productive capacities of<br />

their assets, even when the gains are derived through the efforts of third parties.<br />

Many academic commentators reach the same conclusion, but explain it on the basis<br />

of unjust enrichment."' I confess to remaining sceptical. Neither approach seems to<br />

be sufficiently discriminating. Both lead to results which strip gains equally from<br />

thieves and from innocent donees who fortuitously invest the mistaken gift<br />

profitably, even though they might just as readily have invested their own funds for<br />

their own benefit and left the gift untouched. I prefer an analysis that requires third<br />

parties to disgorge gains only when they have been made in defiance of some<br />

fiduciary obligation to manage the underlying assets in the owner's interests. 9 The<br />

weight of precedent also favours a more restrictive approach: barring the Court of<br />

Appeal case already noted, and one House of Lords case, 60 other instances of true<br />

disgorgement 6 ' all seem to arise in fiduciary contexts. 6 2<br />

56. Sarah Worthington, Justifying Claims to Secondary Profits, in UNJUST ENRICHMENT AND THE<br />

LAW OF CONTRACT 451, 452-53 (E.J.H Schrage ed., 2001).<br />

57. Trustee of the Property of FC Jones & Sons v. Jones, [1997] Ch. 159.<br />

58. See, e.g., Peter Birks, Property, Unjust Enrichment and Tracing, 54 CURRENT LEGAL PROBLEMS<br />

231 (2001); ANDREW BURROWS, THE LAW OF RESTITUTION (2d ed. 2002).<br />

59. WORTHINGTON, EQuITY, supra note 8, at 98-102; Worthington, Justifying Claims to Secondary<br />

Profits, supra note 56, at 451.<br />

60. In Foskett v. McKeown, Lord Millett based his conclusions primarily on the property analysis<br />

adopted in Trustee of the Property of FC Jones, but he also indicated that a fiduciary analysis (which was<br />

possible on the facts) delivers the same conclusions. Foskett v. McKeown, [2001] 1 A.C. 102; Trustee of<br />

the Property of FC Jones & Sons v. Jones, [1997] Ch. 159; see also Lord Millett, Proprietary Restitution, in<br />

EQUITY IN COMMERCIAL LAW, supra note 48.<br />

61. This is rather than compensation (measured by "use value") or restitution for subtractive unjust<br />

enrichment. See Sarah Worthington, Reconsidering Disgorgement for Wrongs, 62 MOD. L. REV. 218<br />

(1999). But see, e.g., JAMES EDELMAN, GAIN-BASED DAMAGES: CONTRACT, TORT, EQUITY AND<br />

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY (2002).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 930 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE DISAPPEARING DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND OBLIGATION<br />

Clearly this area of the law is most unsettled. But the arguments need not be<br />

analysed in detail here. The goal here is simply to determine whether there is a<br />

difference between the legal protections delivered to property and those delivered to<br />

obligation. In the UK at least, this area of the law has prompted vehement debate.<br />

In seeking to protect obligation, commentators have advocated what amounts to<br />

analogous application of the House of Lords' property analysis. They suggest that<br />

contract rights and property rights deserve equivalent protection; that expropriation<br />

of either is inappropriate; and that interference with either should be remedied by<br />

disgorgement in appropriate circumstances. 3 The argument has been used to<br />

support both disgorgement and performance interest damages for breach of<br />

contract; 6' and disgorgement to remedy profitable torts or other wrongs. The cases<br />

do not yet go so far. Disgorgement is available. It is commonly awarded to remedy<br />

fiduciary and other equitable breaches of the claimant's personal right to<br />

confidential or loyal service, even where the fiduciary has not interfered with any<br />

property owned (in equity) by his beneficiary. 6 ' These breaches might be regarded<br />

as interference with the claimant's (personal) right to a particular form of service<br />

from his agent. Early cases suggested that disgorgement was limited to the initial<br />

wrongful gain made by the defaulting fiduciary, and, moreover, that the remedy was<br />

restricted to a personal claim to the value of the gain.' But this approach has now<br />

been radically revised. Full disgorgement of the initial gain and any proceeds<br />

derived from it is favoured; and the remedy is now considered to be proprietary<br />

(delivering insolvency protection to the injured claimant principal). 67 The change in<br />

approach has attracted vocal adherents and equally vocal dissentients. 6 '<br />

Disgorgement has also been advocated as the appropriate remedy for torts,<br />

especially proprietary torts. Some cases can be read as supporting this stance, but it<br />

is equally possible to interpret them as supporting either compensation or<br />

autonomous unjust enrichment claims in respect of the unauthorised use of the<br />

claimant's asset. 6 ' Finally, disgorgement is also available for breach of contract,<br />

62. But see Attorney-General v. Blake (Jonathan Cape Ltd. Third Party), [2001] 1 A.C. 268 (justified<br />

as being a relationship that was very close to fiduciary). This less strict approach is criticised by the Author<br />

and Roy Goode. Sarah Worthington & Roy Goode, Commercial <strong>Law</strong>: Confining the Remedial<br />

Boundaries, in LAW'S FUTURE(S): BRITISH LEGAL DEVELOPMENTS IN THE 21ST CENTURY 281 (David<br />

Hayton ed., 2000).<br />

63. See Lionel D. Smith, Disgorgement of the Profits of a Breach of Contract: Property, Contract and<br />

"Efficient Breach," 24 CAN. BUS. L. J. 121 (1994); Daniel Friedmann, The Efficient Breach Fallacy, 18 J.<br />

LEGAL STUD. 1 (1989).<br />

64. See I.M. Jackman, Restitution for Wrongs, 48 CAMBRIDGE L.J. 302 (1989); Daniel Friedmann, The<br />

Performance Interest in Contract Damages, 111 LAW Q. REV. 628 (1995).<br />

65. Boardman v. Phipps, [1967] 2 A.C. 46.<br />

66. Lister & Co. v. Stubbs, [1890] 45 Ch. D. 1.<br />

67. Att'y Gen. for H.K. v. Reid, [1994] 1 A.C. 324.<br />

68. Some suggest that the remedy should not be proprietary. See, e.g., Roy Goode, Property and<br />

Unjust Enrichment, in ESSAYS ON THE LAW OF RESTITUTION 215 (Andrew Burrows ed., 1991); Roy<br />

Goode, The Recovery of a Director's Improper Gains: Proprietary Remedies for Infringement of Non-<br />

Proprietary Rights, in COMMERCIAL ASPECTS OF TRUSTS AND FIDUCIARY OBLIGATIONS 137 (Ewan<br />

McKendrick ed., 1992). Others suggest that it should perhaps be subordinated to the claims of the<br />

defendant's other creditors. See, e.g., Peter Jaffey, Restitutionary Damages and Disgorgement,<br />

RESTITUTION L. REV. 30, 44 (1995); Vanessa Finch & Sarah Worthington, The Pari Passu Principle and<br />

Ranking Restitutionary Rights, in INSOLVENCY AND RESTITUTION 1, 1-20 (Francis Rose ed., 2000).<br />

69. Wrotham Park Estate Co. Ltd. v. Parkside Homes Ltd., [1974] 1 W.L.R. 798; Penarth Dock Eng'g<br />

Co., Ltd. v. Pounds, [1963] 1 Lloyd's Rep. 359: Whitwham v. Westminster Brymbo Coal & Coke Co.,<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 931 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:917<br />

although the courts insist that this remedy is available only in exceptional<br />

circumstances. 0<br />

What conclusion can be drawn from all of this? Even though the state of the<br />

law remains unsettled, it is clear that there is no sharp divide between property and<br />

obligation in allowing right-holders access to the proceeds of unauthorised<br />

interference with the right. A narrow reading of the authorities (and my preferred<br />

reading) is that both property and obligation are protected in the same way. Both<br />

are typically protected from interference by either compensatory remedies (for torts<br />

or breach of contract) or by restitution (for unjust enrichment); exceptionally, both<br />

are also protected by disgorgement remedies, but only when the infringement is the<br />

result of interference by the right-holder's own fiduciary. The more common, wider,<br />

reading of the authorities reaches quite different conclusions, but is equally strong in<br />

aligning the treatment of property and obligation. This alternative approach sees<br />

both property and obligation as routinely protected by disgorgement remedies. In<br />

short, this attribute of entitlement to proceeds is, like all the others, equally<br />

inadequate in differentiating between property and obligation.<br />

H. Property Rights "Run with the Asset"<br />

Relatively recently, a further distinguishing characteristic of property rights has<br />

been suggested: a property right, unlike a personal right, "'runs with the asset.' 7 .<br />

This sounds promising. It captures an attribute that we do regard as a characteristic<br />

of property. If a thief steals A's car and sells it to C, A's ownership of the car (A's<br />

property rights in the car) run with the car, and can be enforced against C. It does<br />

not matter that A and C are strangers, and have reached no agreement between<br />

themselves about A's rights.<br />

This attribute of rights "running with the asset" is especially attractive if owners<br />

want to divide rights in an asset between several parties, and then allow the<br />

individual parties to deal with their respective rights independently of the other<br />

interest holders. Put generally, if A shares proprietary rights in an asset with B, and<br />

B then transfers the asset to C, will A's interests in the asset persist and be<br />

enforceable against C? The commercial attractions of this result, at least to A, are<br />

clear. This is one of the classical attractions of property rights. But the concomitant<br />

risks to C are equally evident, especially if C is ignorant of A's interests.<br />

In the context of this chapter, two issues need to be resolved. The first is<br />

whether this idea of rights that run with the asset is a characteristic of property<br />

rights; the second is whether the same attribute is also evident with personal rights.<br />

To anticipate, it seems that both property and obligation are, once again, very<br />

similar.<br />

[1896] 2 Ch. 538 (especially 541-2 per Lindley U_). In Strand Electric & Engineering Co. v. Brisford<br />

Entertainments Ltd., it was commented that if the defendant had profited from the use, then disgorgement<br />

of those profits would not be required (per Somervell UJ) or might be (per Denning LJ). Strand Elec. &<br />

Eng'g Co., Ltd. v. Brisford Entm'ts Ltd., [1952] 2 Q.B. 246, 252, 255.<br />

70. Att'y Gen. v. Blake (Jonathan Cape Ltd. Third Party), [2001] 1 A.C. 268; Worthington & Goode,<br />

supra note 62, at 281 (criticizing Att'y Gen. v. Blake); see also Mitchell Mclnnes, Account of Profits for<br />

Common <strong>Law</strong> Wrongs, in EourrY IN COMMERCIAL LAW, supra note 48, at 405,405-30.<br />

71. Hansmann & Kraakman, supra note 36, at 374.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 932 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE DISAPPEARING DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND OBLIGATION<br />

At first sight it seems that the common law, at least, does consider property<br />

rights to run with assets. The earlier example of the theft of A's car is illustrative.<br />

Closer examination shows something different, however. Across a range of property<br />

interests, the real focus seems to be better described as one protecting A only to the<br />

extent that this is consistent with preserving C's rights, unless C knew or ought to<br />

have known of A's competing interests: C is really in the line of sight, not A.<br />

Examples make this clearer. If the subject matter is tangible property, then C<br />

can often be put on notice that others have rights to the asset simply because she<br />

knows that she does not hold those rights: the mere fact of the property's existence is<br />

sufficient indication that other people have rights that need to be respected. 72 She<br />

does not need to know who has those interests; all she needs to know is that she does<br />

not. The physical reality of the property acts as its own form of notice to the world<br />

that someone has interests that merit protection. This form of public notice, or some<br />

marginal variant of it, is used quite commonly. The rule applies to real and personal<br />

tangible property. It also applies to intangible rights that are "marked" by<br />

trademarks or copyright symbols. Strangers are liable, often strictly liable, for<br />

infringements of these ownership or possessory property rights.<br />

But this type of rule has its limits. It works tolerably well in cases of potential<br />

theft, conversion, or trespass to tangible property, where C is made liable for<br />

unilaterally interfering with property rights she knows are not hers, even if she is<br />

unaware of the real owner's identity. The rule seems less apt, however, when an<br />

intermediate party, B, purports to sell or give property rights to C, and C is then<br />

visited with the same remedial consequences because B turns out to be a thief or<br />

fraudster. The physicality of tangible property, or of copyright or trademark<br />

symbols, cannot serve as adequate notice to C if C intends a legitimate acquisition<br />

rather than a unilateral invasion of the relevant rights. 73<br />

The law has developed further strategies to deal with this difficulty. The choice<br />

of different approaches to suit different circumstances appears designed to balance<br />

the fairness and costs of imposing the risk on one party as against the other. There<br />

are two extremes. The first confirms the merits in protecting A's interests, but<br />

recognises the difficulties for C in discovering that these interests exist. The<br />

preferred strategy is then one that enables A to give better notice to the world of his<br />

interests by filing them on a public register. It matters little, it seems, whether the<br />

registry details A's precise interests, 74 or merely provides notice that A has some sort<br />

of interest. 7 " The filing system works because C can then be presumed to know of<br />

72. Merrill & Smith, supra note 37.<br />

73. Notwithstanding this, the common law imposes strict liability for the tort of conversion. See<br />

Andrew Tettenborn, Conversion, Tort and Restitution, in INTERESTS IN GOODS 825 (2d ed., Norman<br />

Palmer & Ewan McKendrick eds., 1998), for a suggestion that conversion's separate functions should be<br />

divided, and liability modified, so that there could be strict liability for recovery (a surrogate vindicatio);<br />

fault based tort liability, based on dishonesty or lack of good faith, enabling compensation for loss from<br />

misuse of the property; and strict liability enabling reversal of unjust enrichments arising from either the<br />

owner's property or its proceeds. In this way, the common law tort-style liability would be brought into<br />

line with the equitable liability for "knowing receipt."<br />

74. As now happens in the U.K. when companies file charges with Companies House. See Companies<br />

Act, 1985, ch. 1, §§ 395-96 (Eng.).<br />

75. This is what happens now in the United <strong>State</strong>s when U.C.C. Article 9 security interests are filed.<br />

The U.K. <strong>Law</strong> Commission proposes adopting this strategy in a reformed U.K. regime. See <strong>Law</strong><br />

Commission, Company Security Interests: A Consultative Report, Consultation Paper No. 176 (2004).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 933 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:917<br />

A's filed interests, whether or not she makes the effort to check the registry. C is<br />

said to have constructive notice of A's filed interests, and A's interests will then<br />

prevail over C's if there is a conflict, even if C has acquired her interests innocently<br />

and for value. There are many illustrations of this strategy in operation: there are<br />

registries of interests in land, certain classes of security interests granted by<br />

corporate borrowers, and ownership of second hand cars.<br />

The second approach is almost the complete reverse of the first. It favours C's<br />

interests over A's, and allows C's interests to prevail so long as she is a bona fide<br />

purchaser for value without notice of A's rights. The rule operates without a register<br />

of A's interests. The burden is thus on A to inform third parties or, more often, to<br />

control the behaviour of his agent, B, to ensure that B does not do anything<br />

unauthorised to defeat A's interests. Put another way, where A and B choose<br />

particular organisational structures to enable them to divide property interests<br />

efficiently between them, then they, not the outsiders (i.e. C), should shoulder the<br />

risk that poor internal management might enable B to deal with C in unauthorised<br />

ways. In these circumstances, A should lose his rights, not C. This protective<br />

strategy is the primary rule that operates when A is a company, B the board of<br />

directors, and C a party dealing with the company. By and large C is allowed to<br />

assume that all of B's advances in dealing with A's assets are authorised, unless C is<br />

either a donee or on notice that the transfer is in defiance of A's legitimate interests.<br />

The same rule applies when A is the beneficiary of a trust, B is a trustee, and C is a<br />

stranger dealing with the trustee over the transfer of the trust assets.<br />

Context helps to define commercial needs, and hence the appropriate style of<br />

rule. Contrast the protection afforded to C in any dealings with currency (the<br />

second style of rule) with those applying to her dealings with goods (the first style of<br />

rule, and with very few registers to assist in improving the protection offered).<br />

As noted earlier, neither the magnitude of this problem, nor the ease of solving<br />

it, is assisted by the numerus clausus rule. As soon as parties wish to divide rights<br />

and deal with them independently, some form of verification or protection is<br />

necessary. This clearly increases the costs well beyond those necessary to operate a<br />

scheme of sole and undivided ownership, but the commercial advantages of division<br />

are overwhelming. Once this is conceded, then, as between a small and large<br />

number of possible divisions (or types) of property rights, the same verification rules<br />

are equally apt. 6 This is easily illustrated. Consider the practicalities of filing: it is<br />

expensive because a registry needs to be established and the parties will incur costs<br />

in filing and in searching, but these costs are not further increased simply because<br />

what is filed is a novel form of private arrangement between A and B.<br />

All of this can be summarised briefly. Property rights may indeed "run with the<br />

asset," so A's rights may be enforceable against C, but only if certain specific<br />

verification or protective rules permit this. These rules aim to balance the burdens<br />

and benefits of a system that permits bundles of rights to be divided, and the divided<br />

parcels to be transferred independently of the other co-owners.<br />

The next issue is the important one for this chapter. Can obligations also "run<br />

with the asset"? Can the same protective strategies be used to achieve similar ends<br />

with obligations as with property?<br />

76. Hansmann & Kraakman, supra note 36.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 934 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE DISAPPEARING DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND OBLIGATION<br />

There is no theoretical or doctrinal reason why the law should not permit this to<br />

happen. Nevertheless, the commercial attractiveness of this in relation to obligations<br />

is far more limited than it is in the case of orthodox property rights. This is because<br />

"contract bundles" are less commonly the object of unauthorised dealings in<br />

defiance of the original contract-holder's rights (as happened in our stolen car<br />

example), and they are less frequently the object of commercially attractive subdivision<br />

that gives different co-owners different interests in an asset. This is when<br />

verification and protective regimes are especially useful. Nevertheless, although the<br />

need for contract rights to run with the asset is less extreme, there are situations<br />

where this would be commercially attractive.<br />

Does the law then allow for this possibility, and adopt the protective strategies<br />

already noted in the context of property? Consider each of the earlier approaches in<br />

turn. Since contract rights are intangible, simple physical notice to the world is<br />

difficult (although there is a sense in which copyright and trademark labels might be<br />

regarded as protecting contract rights, rather than orthodox property rights). That<br />

leaves verification and protective strategies. First consider the use of registers of<br />

intangible assets. These do exist. As with registers of orthodox property rights,<br />

there is no need for registers to record every possible interest in every possible asset.<br />

This is a cost-benefit game. Registers are worth their costs if the rights being filed<br />

are especially valuable, even if the number of filings is relatively small over time<br />

(consider registers of land, ships and aircraft engines), or if the register is used often<br />

and by large numbers of the trading community (consider registers of security<br />

interests or second hand car ownership). Are there registers of "contracts"?<br />

Registers of intellectual property interests, such as patents, can be viewed in this<br />

way. So too can registers of security interests, especially in the United <strong>State</strong>s, where<br />

the courts had denied the proprietary possibility of floating charges. Yet such<br />

contractual arrangements could be effectively enforced by filing under Article 9 of<br />

the United <strong>State</strong>s Uniform Commercial Code. Filing certainly increases the variety<br />

of rights that can be accorded "proprietary" status, in the sense that they run with<br />

the asset. For example, there have been suggestions that negative pledges could<br />

usefully be filed."<br />

The protective strategy is also used with contract rights. This strategy is the<br />

more efficient option where the contract rights are sufficiently valuable to warrant<br />

protection, but the dealings are sufficiently unique to make filing impractical. The<br />

types of contract rights that might warrant this protection are A's right to use B's<br />

assets in a particular manner (as in a contract of hire), or A's claim against B that B<br />

use his property in specified ways, as defined by negative pledge agreements or<br />

agreements to vote shares in a pre-determined manner. In these circumstances, can<br />

A prevent C from using the asset in a manner that is inconsistent with A's<br />

contractual rights? The law remains uncertain, but a line of cases suggests that A<br />

might obtain a negative injunction against C to prevent interference, provided C had<br />

notice of A's rights when she acquired her own interests in the asset. 8<br />

77. Id. at 414 n.79 (citing Barry E. Adler, Financial and Political Theories of American Corporate<br />

Bankruptcy, 45 STAN. L. REV. 311. 336-39 (1993); Barry E. Adler, Secured Credit Contracts, in 3 THE NEW<br />

PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW 405-10 (Peter Newman ed., 1998)).<br />

78. De Mattos v. Gibson, [1858] 45 Eng. Rep. 108 (Ch. 1858); see also WORTHINGTON, PROPRIETARY<br />

INTERESTS, supra note 20, at 101-16.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 935 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:917<br />

When rights recognised by equity were regarded as operating in personam, and<br />

so were seen as personal rather than proprietary, both equity's bona fide purchaser<br />

for value without notice rules and knowing receipt rules could also have been<br />

regarded as major components of the protective regime. This would ensure that<br />

contract rights "ran with the asset" in an appropriate manner. 79<br />

There is a downside to all of this. Any regime that enables rights to run with<br />

the asset also enables increasing fragmentation of rights between different owners,<br />

and this is widely regarded as inefficient. It hampers advantageous dealings with the<br />

underlying asset because it leads to increased transaction costs and the risk of<br />

holdout problems, and these can soon become so large that they frustrate the<br />

efficient use of the asset.8 ° The problem is tempered somewhat by devices like the<br />

rule against perpetuities and limitations of actions. Moreover, registries of rights<br />

promote a market in re-bundling the rights, in much the same way as in the market<br />

for corporate control. Finally, the protective notice regime by its very nature is<br />

unlikely to produce significant fragmentation since A's rights will generally only<br />

persist if C has adequate notice of their existence.<br />

Once again, there seems to be no sharp divide between the law's treatment of<br />

property and obligation in allowing rights to "run with the asset." The differences<br />

that do exist appear to be more closely related to commercial needs than to legal<br />

limitations. The risk of interference and the commercial attractiveness of divided<br />

interests are both greater with orthodox property rights than with purely personal<br />

rights. Where this generalisation does not hold, the law seems to treat both types of<br />

interests in similar ways.<br />

I. Property Rights Attract Insolvency Protection<br />

Insolvency priority is widely regarded as the lynchpin of proprietary<br />

characteristics. Property rights are accorded insolvency protection; personal rights<br />

are not. In reality, this may be the least significant characteristic in making, or<br />

losing, the argument that there is a disappearing divide between property and<br />

obligation. This is because the logic of the property/insolvency link is not associated<br />

in some fundamental way with an attribute that distinguishes property from<br />

obligation. Rather, the distinction depends utterly on current insolvency policy.<br />

Consider two simple examples.<br />

First, suppose X is an individual, but is also the trustee of a trust and the sole<br />

director of a one-man company. If X becomes bankrupt, all the assets that appear to<br />

be his will have to be characterised as relating to one or other of his three different<br />

roles. Some will be personal assets, available to his creditors in his bankruptcy.<br />

Some will relate to the trust. They will not be distributable on X's bankruptcy, but<br />

will be partitioned off and preserved for the trust beneficiaries. Others will belong<br />

to the company. First claim to them will be accorded to the company's creditors, not<br />

79. See generally Lionel Smith, Unraveling Proprietary Restitution, 40 CAN. Bus. L.J. 317 (2004)<br />

(applying a different analysis).<br />

80. In the United <strong>State</strong>s, this is known as the "problem of the anticommons." See Hansmann &<br />

Kraakman, supra note 36, at 417-18 (citing Michael A. Heller, The Tragedy of the Anticommons: Property<br />

in the Transition from Marx to Markets. 111 HARv. L. REV. 621 (1998); and Frank I. Michelman. Ethics,<br />

Economics and the <strong>Law</strong> of Property, in NOMOS XXIV: Ethics, Economics, and the <strong>Law</strong> 3 (J. Ronald<br />

Pencock & John W. Chapman eds., 1982)).<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 936 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE DISAPPEARING DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND OBLIGATION<br />

to X's personal creditors: X's personal interest will be limited to the net value of his<br />

shareholding. This common form of asset partitioning is effected without any<br />

thought of distinguishing between property and obligation. X's personal assets will<br />

include both types of wealth. So too will the trust and corporate assets. Asset<br />

partitioning on insolvency, in this sense, is simply allocating patrimonies to their<br />

appropriate owners (X and the company), and dividing patrimonies between<br />

different roles (X's personal activities and his activities as trustee). In doing this,<br />

there is no property/obligation divide in any sense that is relevant in this chapter.<br />

Take a second case. This tests the property/obligation divide more severely.<br />

Consider the distribution of X's personal assets amongst his own creditors. On X's<br />

insolvency, all his wealth (proprietary and personal) is realised for the benefit of his<br />

creditors. If no creditors have proprietary claims, the entire asset pool will simply be<br />

shared amongst the claimants pro rata. This is regarded as the fairest way to<br />

proceed. By contrast, creditors who can identify an asset as "theirs" can take it,<br />

often in full satisfaction of their claims. The more privileged property-owning<br />

creditors there are, the smaller the pool for the unprivileged personal claimants, and<br />

the smaller the proportion of their losses that will be recovered. Insolvency losses<br />

are thus shifted from the privileged to the unprivileged. If a showroom owner<br />

becomes insolvent, for example, the paid-up purchaser of "the only pink car in the<br />

showroom" can take her car; the paid-up purchaser of "one of the four green cars in<br />

the showroom" cannot. 8 ' Moreover, the latter purchaser cannot specifically recover<br />

his purchase payment, even assuming (rather unrealistically) that he can identify<br />

either it or its traceable substitutes amongst the debtor's assets. 82 Many creditors are<br />

in this unsecured position, unless they take security to preserve their interests.<br />

Why does insolvency law permit this difference in treatment between different<br />

creditors, and, in our example, between different purchaser creditors? Elsewhere, I<br />

have called this the "musical chairs" element of insolvency law: the result for<br />

different creditors depends entirely on the timing of the debtor's insolvency (that is,<br />

on the timing of when the music stops). 83 The justification is relatively simple. The<br />

task of insolvency law is to maximise returns to all creditors by effecting an orderly<br />

distribution of the debtor's assets. This goal is best achieved by a co-coordinated<br />

distribution process. Furthermore, viable enterprises should not be tipped into<br />

insolvency; this is unnecessarily costly for all concerned. The best mechanism to<br />

ensure these twin goals are met, and that creditors have no incentive to steal a march<br />

by acting unilaterally or to tip the debtor into early insolvency, is to insist that the<br />

pre- and post-insolvency rights of all creditors remain the same. There is then no<br />

situational advantage for anyone in moving the debtor into insolvency. This<br />

reasoning means that pre-insolvency property rights must be preserved, and in turn<br />

post-insolvency priority given to property owners.<br />

The ability of creditors to take legal security (by means of proprietary interests)<br />

to preserve their priority is subjected to the same form of insolvency justification. In<br />

the end, security is seen as advantageous because it increases commercial activity.<br />

81. Sale of Goods Act, 1979, 28 & 29 Eliz. 2, c. 54, §§ 16-18 (Eng.).<br />

82. In re Goldcorp Exchange Ltd. (in rec.), [1995] 1 A.C. 74 (P.C. 1994) (appeal taken from New<br />

Zealand).<br />

83. Sarah Worthington, Proprietary Remedies and Insolvency Policy: The Need for a New Approach,<br />

in COMMERCIAL LAW: PERSPECTIVES AND PRACTICE 191 (John Lowry & L Mistelis eds., 2006)<br />

[hereinafter Worthington, Proprietary Remedies and Insolvency Policy].<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 937 2006-2007


TEXAS INTERNATIONAL LAW JOURNAL<br />

VOL. 42:917<br />

Parties who would not otherwise have access to funds for business (or domestic)<br />

expansion and development can make use of these resources. In any event,<br />

pragmatism suggests that commercial parties would make arrangements designed to<br />

achieve the same ends, at greater cost, if the law did not provide a structured<br />

mechanism. Nevertheless, parliament restricts the availability of this form of<br />

insolvency protection by imposing registration requirements and, in some cases,<br />

timing, vulnerability, and claw-back limitations."<br />

All of this makes perfect sense, and yet there is a gnawing reluctance to push<br />

this preferential proprietary analysis too far. As already noted, the Insolvency Act<br />

1986 (U.K.) itself imposes limitations on the effectiveness of security. It also accords<br />

preferential status to certain contract rights, especially employee rights, on<br />

insolvency. 85 And when property priority is delivered in the form of a proprietary<br />

remedy from the debtor, the courts are increasingly alert to the adverse implications<br />

for the unsecured creditors. 86 Civil law jurisdictions are much happier to insist that<br />

some of these remedial property claims are contingent, not privileged. The United<br />

<strong>State</strong>s is more restrictive than the United Kingdom. Indeed, the United <strong>State</strong>s<br />

Uniform Commercial Code Article 9 filing regime, for all its assertions that property<br />

rights are proprietary, has effectively replaced the common law proprietary system<br />

of security with a statutory priorities system for obligations. Priority rules have<br />

replaced property rules. This makes it easier for the legislature to amend priorities<br />

without affecting non-insolvency property rights.<br />

This complicated common law and statutory hierarchy of insolvency rights<br />

could be changed. There is nothing inevitable about the insolvency protection<br />

accorded to property rights.7 Theoretically, the system could deliver preferential<br />

status according to some completely different regime, perhaps according to the type<br />

of claim being advanced by the creditor. This would involve prioritising certain<br />

forms of claim over other forms, and ignoring whether or not they have traditionally<br />

been regarded as proprietary or not. This would overcome the problem that some<br />

claims, by their very nature, can never attach to any specific part of the pool of<br />

debtor's assets, and yet these claims may well be thought more worthy than others<br />

that are able to assert such an attachment. Elsewhere I have argued that this sort of<br />

analysis may suggest that unjust enrichment claims should be given insolvency<br />

privileges above those accorded to compensation claims.' Put more generally,<br />

insolvency is all about policy, and sharing losses amongst innocent parties. As a<br />

matter of policy, it is important to consider carefully the pre- and post-insolvency<br />

goals, and decide which rights should legitimately be privileged.<br />

84. Companies Act, 1995, §§ 395-96 (Eng.); Insolvency Act 1986, c. 45, § 245, sched. B1 para. 70<br />

(Eng.).<br />

85. See Insolvency Act 1986, c. 45, §§ 40, 175(2)(b), 176A (§ 176A is a recent addition to the Act).<br />

86. Recall the excitement over Att'y Gen. for H.K. v. Reid, [1994] 1 A.C. 324 (P.C. 1993) (appeal<br />

taken from New Zealand). See, e.g., In Re Goldcorp Exchange Ltd. (in rec.), [1995] 1 A.C. 74 (P.C. 1994)<br />

(appeal taken from New Zealand); Westdeutsche Landesbank Girozentrale v. Islington London Borough<br />

Council, [1996] A.C. 669 (H.L.); Agnew v. Comm'r of Inland Revenue, [20011 2 A.C. 710 (P.C.). But see In<br />

Re Polly Peck Int'l PLC (in admin) (No 4), [1998] 3 All Eng. Rep. 812, 826-27 (opinion by Mummery LJ,<br />

varying in analysis from previously cited cases).<br />

87. See generally Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Jesse M. Fried, The Uneasy Case for the Priority of Secured<br />

Claims in Bankruptcy, 105 YALE L.J. 857 (1996); Worthington, Proprietary Remedies and Insolvency<br />

Policy, supra note 83; see also Sarah Worthington, Property, Obligation and Insolvency Policy: Cutting the<br />

Gordian Knot, 20 J. INT'L BANKING & FINANCIAL LAW 100 (2005) (making a shorter version of the same<br />

argument).<br />

88. Finch & Worthington, supra note 68.<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 938 2006-2007


2007<br />

THE DISAPPEARING DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND OBLIGATION<br />

In summary, insolvency priority is currently treated as a defining characteristic<br />

of property, distinguishing it from obligation. The implications for the respective<br />

right holders are dramatic. Those with property rights often recover in full. This<br />

leaves a disproportionately diminished pool of assets for the personal right holders<br />

to share. The result is that they often receive nothing. This is all the more worrying<br />

when, as the rest of this chapter shows, we are becoming increasingly uncertain<br />

about how to classify rights as falling on one side of this privileged dividing line.<br />

III. Is DISAPPEARANCE OF THE DIVIDE BETWEEN PROPERTY AND<br />

OBLIGATION SIGNIFICANT?<br />

The significance of the conclusion that there is no longer any sharp divide<br />

between property and obligation depends upon your perspective. If given any<br />

credence, it will end the search for the Holy Grail, and that in itself might liberate a<br />

significant amount of academic effort.<br />

Why do we have property? It is said to be necessary for all advanced and<br />

advancing societies to ensure greater productivity and commitment to effort. Parties<br />

who own assets know that they will derive the fruits of their labour, and they are<br />

then prepared to expend greater efforts. It is immediately obvious, however, that<br />

property is surplus to this equation, aside from making the point that common or<br />

community ownership does not work. Ensuring that not all wealth or property is<br />

held in common provides an incentive. This is as true of personal rights as it is of<br />

property rights.<br />

On other fronts, too, the news of a merger is not dramatic. But this is not<br />

because the news itself lacks dramatic impact. Rather it is that we arrived at this<br />

position quite some time ago and have had time to adjust to the consequences.<br />

Centuries ago, commercial parties saw that all rights, whether contract or property,<br />

could perform as usable wealth. They then adapted their practices accordingly.<br />

Economists were next to appreciate that these rights have merged. The lawyers<br />

have lagged behind. 8 9 Perhaps it is time to catch up.<br />

89. But c.f ROSCOE POUND, AN INTRODUCTION TO THE PHILOSOPHY OF LAW 236 (1922) ("Wealth,<br />

in a commercial age, is made up largely of promises.")<br />

HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 939 2006-2007


HeinOnline -- 42 Tex. Int'l L.J. 940 2006-2007

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!