20.10.2014 Views

A Reformed CDM including new Mechanisms for - CD4CDM

A Reformed CDM including new Mechanisms for - CD4CDM

A Reformed CDM including new Mechanisms for - CD4CDM

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Perspectives Series 2008<br />

A <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>med</strong> <strong>CDM</strong><br />

– <strong>including</strong> <strong>new</strong> <strong>Mechanisms</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

Sustainable Development


Perspectives Series 2008<br />

A <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>med</strong> <strong>CDM</strong><br />

– <strong>including</strong> <strong>new</strong> <strong>Mechanisms</strong><br />

<strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development<br />

Karen Holm Olsen<br />

Jørgen Fenhann<br />

Editors<br />

UNEP Risø Centre


Contents<br />

Editorial 5<br />

Karen Holm Olsen, Jørgen Fenhann<br />

Sustainable development and equity<br />

Market <strong>Mechanisms</strong> <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development<br />

in a Post-2012 Climate Regime:<br />

Implications <strong>for</strong> the Development Dividend 9<br />

Deborah Murphy, Aaron Cosbey, John Drexhage<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> in Brazil:<br />

Towards Structural Change <strong>for</strong><br />

Sustainable Development in Some Sectors 23<br />

Branca Americano<br />

Legal Influences Perspectives<br />

from Africa on a <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>med</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> 35<br />

David Lesolle<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong>, ethics and development 47<br />

Diana Liverman, Emily Boyd<br />

Institutional re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

Does the <strong>CDM</strong> need an institutional re<strong>for</strong>m? 59<br />

Hans Jürgen Stehr<br />

A re<strong>for</strong>med <strong>CDM</strong> to increase supply:<br />

Room <strong>for</strong> action 73<br />

Benoît Leguet, Ghada Elabed,<br />

<strong>CDM</strong><br />

Developing Country Financing<br />

<strong>for</strong> Developed Country Commitments? 85<br />

By Søren E. LütkenPh.D<br />

The Clean Development Mechanism:<br />

Assessment of Experience and<br />

Expectations <strong>for</strong> the Future 101<br />

DUAN Maosheng


expansion of project categories<br />

Re<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>CDM</strong> and Scaling-Up<br />

Finance <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Urban Transport 111<br />

Sergio Sanchez<br />

scaling Up Energy Efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong> 127<br />

Anne Arquit Niederberger<br />

scaling up mitigation<br />

sector No-Lose Targets:<br />

a New Scaling Up Mechanism For Developing Countries 147<br />

Murray Ward<br />

Scaling Up Ghg Emission Reductions<br />

through Replicable Business Models 163<br />

Francisco Avendaño<br />

LULUCF under <strong>CDM</strong>:<br />

is there a role or even a future<br />

in the post-2012 regime? 173<br />

Marcelo Theoto Rocha


Capacity Development <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> (CD4<strong>CDM</strong>) Project<br />

UNEP Risø Centre,<br />

Risø National Laboratory <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Energy<br />

The Technical University of Denmark<br />

Box 49<br />

DK-4000 Roskilde,<br />

Denmark<br />

Tel: +45-4632 2288<br />

Fax: +45-4632 1999<br />

www.uneprisoe.org<br />

www.cd4cdm.org<br />

ISBN 978-87-550-3715-1<br />

Graphic design:<br />

Finn Hagen Madsen, Graphic Design<br />

Copenhagen, Denmark<br />

Printed by:<br />

Schultz, Denmark.<br />

Printed on environmentally friendly paper.<br />

Disclaimer<br />

The findings, opinions, interpretations and conclusions expressed in this report are entirely those of the authors and should<br />

not be attributed in any manner to the UNEP Risø Center, the United Nations Environment Program, the Technical University<br />

of Denmark, the Netherlands Ministry of Foreign Affairs, nor to the respective organizations of each individual author.


Karen Holm Olsen<br />

Jørgen Fenhann<br />

Editors<br />

UNEP Risø Centre<br />

Editorial<br />

Two things can be said about the <strong>CDM</strong>: it has<br />

been successful in creating a dynamic carbon<br />

market, and it can certainly be improved. Since<br />

the Kyoto Protocol entered into <strong>for</strong>ce in 2005,<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> has developed very rapidly, with more<br />

than 4000 projects in the pipeline and a further<br />

120 <strong>new</strong> projects entering the pipeline every<br />

month. Together, these projects represent a<br />

cumulative expected total of 2.8 billion tonnes<br />

of reductions by 2012. In a very short time, the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> has mobilised billions of dollars in public<br />

and private investment to reduce emissions in<br />

developing countries.<br />

In the decade since the Kyoto Protocol was<br />

established and the <strong>CDM</strong> conceptualized, it<br />

has become clear that the world has become a<br />

very different place. From the warm and tranquil<br />

beaches of Bali <strong>for</strong> COP 13 to the COP 14 in a<br />

much cooler Poland, global awareness of climate<br />

change has accelerated, along with serious<br />

concerns about the global economy. It is no small<br />

irony that a looming global economic slowdown<br />

could achieve the equivalent of all current<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>’s reductions in a fraction of the time, but<br />

this is evidently not an attractive way to reduce<br />

emissions.<br />

At the same time, the <strong>CDM</strong> has encountered a<br />

number of challenges and weaknesses, <strong>including</strong><br />

unequal regional distribution of projects, concerns<br />

about environmental integrity and technology<br />

transfer, complex governance procedures, and<br />

questions about the <strong>CDM</strong>’s contribution to<br />

sustainable development.<br />

This edition of Perspectives tries to answer the<br />

question, “Where to from here?” In other words:<br />

“How to re<strong>for</strong>m the <strong>CDM</strong> in a post-2012 climate<br />

regime?”<br />

Irony aside, the global economic crisis also<br />

presents an enormous opportunity to ‘lock in’<br />

emission reductions when the global economy<br />

eventually rebounds. This can only happen,<br />

however, if global businesses and governments<br />

pursue very much a “business unusual” approach.<br />

UNEP’s Executive Director, Achim Steiner, has<br />

called <strong>for</strong> a “New Green Deal”, citing “the flip side”<br />

of the current crisis as the enormous economic,<br />

social and environmental benefits that are likely<br />

to arise from combating climate change and reinvesting<br />

in natural infrastructure, with “benefits<br />

5<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


anging from <strong>new</strong> green jobs in clean tech and<br />

clean energy businesses up to ones in sustainable<br />

agriculture and conservation-based enterprises”.<br />

For the <strong>CDM</strong>, these <strong>for</strong>ces will shape the continuing<br />

negotiations <strong>for</strong> a post-2012 climate change agreement.<br />

Increasingly these negotiations are focused<br />

on three issues:<br />

• Deeper emission cuts by all developed<br />

countries;<br />

• Adaptation support in least-developed<br />

countries and small island countries<br />

that are most vulnerable to climate<br />

change; and<br />

• Attracting and enabling greater participation<br />

by developing countries to reduce<br />

emissions.<br />

Following the Bali Action Plan, the <strong>CDM</strong> and<br />

adaptation are two major ways to attract the<br />

participation of developing countries, which<br />

have agreed to undertake quantifiable emission<br />

reductions. To achieve this, developed countries<br />

have agreed to provide the measurable, reportable<br />

and verifiable technical and financial means<br />

required.<br />

The challenge being most discussed now is how to<br />

build on the existing <strong>CDM</strong> to create much greater<br />

participation from developing countries post-<br />

2012 that can help them transit substantially to<br />

a development path free from damaging carbon<br />

emissions. Perhaps the <strong>CDM</strong> needs to move from<br />

a project-based level to a sector or programmebased<br />

level, as suggested by India’s ambassador<br />

and <strong>for</strong>mer climate negotiator, Chandrashekar<br />

Dasgupta.<br />

Henry Ford was fond of reminding his staff that<br />

“everything can be done better than it is”. In this<br />

spirit, Perspectives explores how the <strong>CDM</strong> can be<br />

improved as negotiators prepare <strong>for</strong> a post-2012<br />

climate agreement. In these pages, you will find<br />

diverse insights on re<strong>for</strong>ming and rein<strong>for</strong>cing<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> in a post-2012 climate regime from<br />

seventeen leading actors in the rapidly developing<br />

carbon market. The goal of compiling these views<br />

is to better in<strong>for</strong>m the decisions of professionals<br />

and policy-makers in the lead-up to COP 15 in<br />

Copenhagen and beyond.<br />

The thirteen papers in this Perspectives raises four<br />

key issues:<br />

Sustainable development and equity<br />

Working <strong>for</strong> the International Institute <strong>for</strong><br />

Sustainable Development (IISD) in Canada,<br />

Murphy et al. examine the implications <strong>for</strong><br />

the Development Dividend of four different<br />

climate-regime options in a post-2012 regime.<br />

Positioned in the DNA of Brazil, Americano<br />

asks to what extent the <strong>CDM</strong> has contributed<br />

towards trans<strong>for</strong>mational change <strong>for</strong> sustainable<br />

development in some sectors. Lesolle’s perspective<br />

from Botswana explores <strong>CDM</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms to achieve<br />

a more equitable geographical distribution of<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> projects with benefits <strong>for</strong> African countries.<br />

The fourth paper by Liverman and Boyd presents<br />

ethical and development issues in the <strong>CDM</strong> from<br />

an academic perspective in Britain.<br />

Institutional re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

Maosheng takes stock of the <strong>CDM</strong>’s per<strong>for</strong>mance<br />

to date and offers a Chinese perspective on<br />

expectations <strong>for</strong> the future, <strong>including</strong> how<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> can be scaled up to promote its<br />

current objectives further. Based on personal<br />

experience as the Chairman of the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Executive Board <strong>for</strong> two terms, Stehr analyses<br />

and discusses the need <strong>for</strong> an institutional<br />

re<strong>for</strong>m of the <strong>CDM</strong>. Lequet and Elabed from<br />

France ask how procedural changes to the<br />

existing institutional framework may increase<br />

the supply of emission reductions. Lütken, a<br />

6CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Dane working <strong>for</strong> a Dutch company in China,<br />

proposes ways of dealing with the challenges<br />

of the prevailing unilateral, developing<br />

country financing of <strong>CDM</strong> projects, and the<br />

lack of technology transfer.<br />

Expansion of project categories<br />

Sanchez, from the US-based Clean Air<br />

Institute, focuses on the transport sector and<br />

asks how the <strong>CDM</strong> may be improved <strong>for</strong> this<br />

sector, while Niederberger, a senior expert on<br />

end-use energy efficiency from Switzerland,<br />

presents a vision <strong>for</strong> a <strong>CDM</strong> contributing to a<br />

global scaling up of energy efficiency.<br />

Scaling up mitigation<br />

Sector-no-lose-targets (SNLTs), a possible<br />

<strong>new</strong> carbon-market mechanism <strong>for</strong> scaling<br />

up investment in low-carbon technology in<br />

developing countries, is presented by Ward, a<br />

<strong>for</strong>mer negotiator from New Zealand. Rocha,<br />

a <strong>for</strong>estry expert in Brazil, asks if there is<br />

a role to play <strong>for</strong> land use, land use change<br />

and <strong>for</strong>estry (LULUCF) under <strong>CDM</strong> in a post-<br />

2012 regime, <strong>including</strong> options to finance<br />

reduced emissions from de<strong>for</strong>estation and<br />

<strong>for</strong>est degradation (REDD). Avendaño from<br />

Peru looks at Programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> and asks<br />

how replicable business models from other<br />

commodity markets can help mature the<br />

carbon market through management entities<br />

developing a secondary supply of carbon<br />

credits.<br />

The success of the <strong>CDM</strong> has demonstrated the<br />

value of carbon markets as one tool to achieve<br />

internationally agreed political targets, but<br />

there are still concerns to be addressed and <strong>new</strong><br />

mechanisms <strong>for</strong> sustainable development to be<br />

considered.<br />

Given the increased complexity of a <strong>new</strong> climate<br />

agreement, it is likely that a re<strong>for</strong>med <strong>CDM</strong> will<br />

stick to what is desired by almost all Parties −<br />

increased environmental integrity, simplified<br />

governance, achievement of sustainable develop<br />

ment benefits, and flexibility towards programmes<br />

and policies. A transition towards<br />

a graduation process, with some of the large<br />

emitting developing countries moving from being<br />

eligible <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> project-hosting to some other<br />

<strong>for</strong>m of technical and financial support, is being<br />

discussed in the negotiations. It will probably not<br />

happen in Copenhagen, but this or other <strong>new</strong><br />

approaches could be built into a review process,<br />

leaving some of the tough negotiations and<br />

needed analytical understanding to be worked<br />

out over time.<br />

We hope this issue of Perspectives<br />

contributes to this goal.<br />

The UNEP Risø Centre Energy<br />

and Carbon Finance Group<br />

Introduction<br />

7<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


8CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Deborah Murphy,<br />

Aaron Cosbey<br />

John Drexhage<br />

International Institute <strong>for</strong><br />

Sustainable Development<br />

Market <strong>Mechanisms</strong> <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development<br />

in a Post-2012 Climate Regime:<br />

Implications <strong>for</strong> the<br />

Development Dividend<br />

Abstract<br />

There is broad consensus in the international<br />

talks on a post-2012 climate change regime<br />

on the need <strong>for</strong> some perpetuation of the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>—a market mechanism <strong>for</strong> sustainable<br />

development (MMSD). Regime options under<br />

discussion will impact on the “development<br />

dividend” of a post-2012 MMSD, affecting<br />

quality (sustainable development), quantity<br />

(volume of CERs) and regional distribution. This<br />

paper examines four regime options—increasing<br />

the scope of the <strong>CDM</strong> to include additional<br />

sectors, differentiation of developing country<br />

eligibility, expanding the <strong>CDM</strong>, and a fund-based<br />

mechanism—and their potential impacts on the<br />

three elements of the development dividend.<br />

The nature and scope of the Clean Development<br />

Mechanism (<strong>CDM</strong>) is an important consideration<br />

in the international discussions on a post-2012<br />

climate change regime. The negotiations have<br />

taken on increased intensity as negotiators seek<br />

to finalize a post-2012 regime by COP 15 in<br />

December 2009. The Bali Action Plan, adopted in<br />

December 2007, set out broad parameters to guide<br />

the two-year negotiating process, focusing on<br />

mitigation, adaptation, technology development<br />

and transfer, and financing and investment.<br />

The Plan also emphasized the importance of<br />

“Various approaches, <strong>including</strong> opportunities<br />

<strong>for</strong> using markets, in order to enhance the costeffectiveness<br />

of, and to promote, mitigation<br />

actions, bearing in mind different circumstances<br />

of developed and developing countries” (United<br />

Nations Framework Convention on Climate<br />

Change [UNFCCC], 2007a: 2). The current regime<br />

employs the <strong>CDM</strong> and Joint Implementation (JI)<br />

as market mechanisms, but one can imagine<br />

a number of different market mechanisms <strong>for</strong><br />

9<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


sustainable development (MMSD) that could<br />

play similar roles. 1<br />

Discussions at the UN meetings indicate that the<br />

current <strong>CDM</strong> could be subject to major changes<br />

in any post-2012 climate agreement. The Ad<br />

Hoc Working Group on Further Commitments<br />

<strong>for</strong> Annex I Parties under the Kyoto Protocol<br />

(AWG-KP) is deliberating possible improvements<br />

to the project-based mechanisms. Key elements<br />

being explored include broadening the scope of<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> to include other activities (land use,<br />

land-use change and <strong>for</strong>estry (LULUCF), carbon<br />

capture and storage (CCS) and nuclear); and<br />

expanding the <strong>CDM</strong> to include sectoral <strong>CDM</strong>,<br />

sectoral crediting of emission reductions below<br />

a previously established no-lose target, and/or<br />

crediting on the basis of nationally appropriate<br />

mitigation actions (NAMA). Also under discussion<br />

are proposals to improve the functioning of<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong>, <strong>including</strong> standardized baselines<br />

and positive or negative lists of project activity<br />

types to improve environmental integrity and<br />

the assessment of additionality; differentiation<br />

of eligibility of partners; improved access to the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong> least developed countries (LDCs) and<br />

small island developing states (SIDS); co-benefits<br />

as a criteria <strong>for</strong> registration; and multiplication<br />

factors to increase or decrease Certified<br />

Emissions Reductions (CERs) issued <strong>for</strong> specific<br />

project types.<br />

Evident from these discussions is that most, if<br />

not all, UNFCCC Parties envision an important<br />

role <strong>for</strong> a <strong>CDM</strong>-like mechanism in the post-<br />

2012 regime. Yet there are different views of<br />

1 In this paper, MMSD describes a market mechanism that can be<br />

used to achieve the goals of the current <strong>CDM</strong> as stated in Article 12 of<br />

the Kyoto Protocol, “to assist Parties not included in Annex I in achieving<br />

sustainable development and in contributing to the ultimate objective<br />

of the Convention, and to assist Parties included in Annex I in achieving<br />

compliance with their quantified emission limitation and reduction commitments.”<br />

what constitutes an effective and appropriate<br />

mechanism. Many developed countries are<br />

interested in an MMSD that provides access<br />

to low cost credits to meet compliance targets<br />

under the Kyoto Protocol. But there are growing<br />

concerns about international offsets, with some<br />

viewing them as a wealth transfer, arguing that<br />

the current <strong>CDM</strong> market does not reflect actual<br />

reductions in emissions (Victor and Wara, 2008).<br />

Political sentiment in developed countries<br />

requires robust additionality processes to ensure<br />

the environmental integrity of credits under an<br />

MMSD. Developed countries are also interested<br />

in an MMSD as a means to engage developing<br />

countries in ef<strong>for</strong>ts to reduce emissions and to<br />

encourage large emitting countries to go beyond<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> in the post-2012 regime.<br />

Developing countries see the mechanism as an<br />

important means <strong>for</strong> supporting sustainable<br />

development, and are careful to safeguard<br />

their sovereign right to define what constitutes<br />

sustainable development in the national context.<br />

For most, it includes at least increases in the flow<br />

of investments, technology transfer and access<br />

to leading-edge clean technologies. Equity of<br />

access and the regional distribution of projects<br />

under the mechanism is particularly a concern<br />

<strong>for</strong> LDCs. Developing countries also want an<br />

MMSD that keeps demand robust. While this is<br />

dependent on governments reaching agreement<br />

on further greenhouse gas (GHG) emission<br />

reduction targets, the structure of the mechanism<br />

will have a bearing on supply and demand post-<br />

2012. As well, they are conscious of the fact that<br />

the integrity of the mechanism will also have an<br />

impact on demand from Annex I Parties, CERs<br />

being only one of several options <strong>for</strong> Annex I<br />

compliance via trading. 2<br />

2 Currently, two other market-based mechanisms offer compliance<br />

units <strong>for</strong> Annex I Parties: Assigned Amount Units (AAUs) under International<br />

Emissions Trading (IET) and Emissions Reduction Units (ERUs)<br />

under JI.<br />

10<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


An effective MMSD in a post-2012 regime will<br />

need to balance the demands and expectations<br />

of developed and developing countries, <strong>including</strong><br />

addressing the issues of quality, quantity and<br />

regional distribution of projects—characteristics<br />

of the “Development Dividend” (Cosbey et al.,<br />

2005). From a development dividend perspective,<br />

this means understanding how the future regimes<br />

could assist in improving:<br />

• Quality – encouraging stronger sustainable<br />

development in developing<br />

countries;<br />

• Quantity – ensuring access to cost-effective<br />

CERs that are commensurate with market<br />

demand, and encouraging large-scale<br />

investments in trans<strong>for</strong>ma-tive sectors<br />

such as energy and transpor-tation;<br />

• Regional distribution – increasing<br />

investment in LDCs and other poor<br />

developing nations. 3<br />

The paper examines possible post-2012 regime<br />

structures, the potential role of the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

or other MMSD within the structures,<br />

and the implications <strong>for</strong> the development<br />

dividend within each regime. To guide the<br />

analysis, the paper examines four possible<br />

regime options that are being discussed<br />

in the international negotiations:<br />

• Targets with flexibility mechanisms:<br />

• Differentiation of developing country<br />

eligibility;<br />

• Expanded <strong>CDM</strong>; and<br />

4<br />

• Fund-based Mechanism.<br />

3 IISD’s on-going Development Dividend Project explores what can be<br />

done to improve the quality, quantity and regional distribution of <strong>CDM</strong><br />

projects. Project in<strong>for</strong>mation and reports can be found at: http://www.<br />

iisd.org/climate/global/dividend.asp.<br />

4 This discussion builds on an earlier IISD paper (Cosbey, Murphy<br />

and Drexhage, 2007) that surveyed 43 proposed post-2012 regime<br />

approaches to see what they implied <strong>for</strong> MMSDs. The 2007 survey also<br />

looked at technology approaches and concluded that such approaches, in<br />

and of themselves, do not include a role <strong>for</strong> an MMSD. Some technology<br />

actions could incorporate “market-plus” elements, such as carbon offsets;<br />

In Sections 2 to 5, each of the four options is<br />

examined, looking at regime characteristics and<br />

implications <strong>for</strong> the development dividend. The<br />

discussion on quality asks what the various regime<br />

options would mean <strong>for</strong> an MMSD’s potential<br />

to contribute to sustainable development. The<br />

quantity discussion explores the implications of<br />

the regime options <strong>for</strong> the volume of CERs in the<br />

market. The discussion on regional distribution<br />

Cosbey and Drexhage (2007) argue that<br />

there will be pressure <strong>for</strong> major developing<br />

countries to take actions commensurate<br />

with their capacity, which could include an<br />

expansion of Kyoto’s simple two-tiered system.<br />

assesses the potential impacts of the regime<br />

options on the share of MMSD investment<br />

destined <strong>for</strong> least developed and poorer<br />

countries. Section 6 provides an overview of the<br />

four regime options and concluding comments.<br />

Targets with Flexibility <strong>Mechanisms</strong><br />

A number of proposed post-2012 regimes being<br />

discussed in the international negotiations<br />

accommodate the <strong>CDM</strong> in more or less its current<br />

<strong>for</strong>m. While many proposals suggest elements<br />

of improvement and streamlining, the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

remains a project-based mechanism, albeit with<br />

programmes of activities. It operates within a<br />

regime that includes emission reduction targets,<br />

and differentiation between those with targets<br />

and those without. This is fairly straight<strong>for</strong>ward,<br />

and currently includes Annex I and non-Annex<br />

but these are not discussed in this current paper as there is little experience<br />

with technology credits (aside from sectoral-based approaches,<br />

which are included under the expanded <strong>CDM</strong> category).<br />

Implications <strong>for</strong> the Development Dividend<br />

11<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


I countries, where the <strong>CDM</strong> acts as a bridge<br />

between these two types of groups.<br />

The AWG-KP discussions include proposals that<br />

would maintain the basic project-based structure<br />

of the <strong>CDM</strong>, but expand the scope to include<br />

additional eligible project activities, <strong>including</strong><br />

other LULUCF, CCS and nuclear activities<br />

(UNFCCC, 2008).<br />

Development Dividend Implications<br />

Quality - The extent to which the <strong>CDM</strong> has<br />

contributed to sustainable development has<br />

been a major point of contention <strong>for</strong> many<br />

stakeholders and some have asserted that the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> has not lived up to expectations in this<br />

regard. All <strong>CDM</strong> host countries are required to<br />

assess projects to ensure that they are compatible<br />

with their sustainable development objectives.<br />

And there have been a range of different<br />

approaches adopted by countries in terms of<br />

how they screen projects <strong>for</strong> achievement of<br />

these objectives. HFC-23 destruction and N 2<br />

O<br />

projects are the most contentious in this regard.<br />

CCS and nuclear projects have the potential to<br />

generate similar criticisms about their inability<br />

to contribute to sustainable development,<br />

and their potential to divert investments from<br />

re<strong>new</strong>able and energy efficiency—project areas<br />

with greater sustainable development benefits.<br />

There is no guarantee that negotiators will agree<br />

on <strong>including</strong> these project sectors in a post-2012<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>, but a possible solution <strong>for</strong> the quality issue,<br />

while not necessarily ideal, could be the levying<br />

of a tax on such projects with revenues put<br />

into a national sustainable development fund.<br />

This would be similar to systems already taxing<br />

the proceeds from carbon credit sales such as in<br />

China, Egypt and Vietnam. Such a solution is unlikely<br />

to be part of an international agreement<br />

and action would need to take place unilaterally<br />

at the country level.<br />

Also, under discussion is the possibility of <strong>including</strong><br />

co-benefits as criteria <strong>for</strong> the registration of <strong>CDM</strong><br />

project activities (UNFCCC, 2008), <strong>including</strong><br />

specific sustainable development benefits. The<br />

prospects of reaching such an agreement are low,<br />

as developing countries most likely will hold fast<br />

to their right to define sustainable development.<br />

Quantity – Modifying the scope of eligible project<br />

activities has the potential to unlock a huge<br />

potential supply of credits at low prices. A study<br />

from the Woods Hole Research Center concluded<br />

that 94 percent of Amazon de<strong>for</strong>estation could<br />

be avoided at a cost of less than US$5 per tonne,<br />

compared to the US$25-35 per tonne trading<br />

range of existing CERs (Nepstad, et al., 2007). If<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> revenues were available to boost incentives<br />

in this area, a large amount of cheap credits could<br />

potentially become available on the market—<br />

creating concerns of over-supply. This, combined<br />

with a potential increase in credits from CCS and<br />

nuclear projects (as well as sectoral credits and<br />

crediting on the basis of nationally appropriate<br />

mitigation actions, discussed in Section 4), could<br />

completely swamp the market.<br />

Of course, this depends on the broader<br />

international agreement. If there was agreement<br />

to limit global average temperature increase to<br />

2°C compared to pre-industrial levels, the supply<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong> credits may not be able to meet demand.<br />

And political sentiment in developed nations may<br />

result in less desire <strong>for</strong> meeting targets through<br />

international purchases—favoring domestic<br />

action or other compliance credits—dampening<br />

demand.<br />

12<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Regional distribution – A wider scope of LULUCF<br />

projects could encourage broader participation<br />

in the <strong>CDM</strong>. There is huge potential in non-Annex<br />

I countries <strong>for</strong> LULUCF projects in addition<br />

to af<strong>for</strong>estation and re<strong>for</strong>estation—such as<br />

improved agriculture, reducing the unsustainable<br />

use of biomass energy, revegetation, and reducing<br />

emissions from de<strong>for</strong>estation and degradation<br />

(REDD). 5 Indeed, Schlamadinger’s (2007) research<br />

determined that a broader LULUCF scope could<br />

help ensure a more regional distribution of <strong>CDM</strong><br />

projects, especially <strong>for</strong> Africa. It is the position<br />

of the African Group that REDD should be<br />

considered under the project-based mechanisms<br />

to help improve regional equity; and the LDC<br />

negotiating group has called <strong>for</strong> a broadening to<br />

LULUCF activities to allow greater access <strong>for</strong> LDCs<br />

to the <strong>CDM</strong> (Third World Network, 2008a: 3).<br />

In regard to broadening the scope to include<br />

CCS and nuclear, there is some concern that<br />

such projects would continue to benefit the<br />

larger, more economically-advanced developing<br />

nations. The UNEP-Risoe Centre’s (2008)<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> pipeline indicates that the top three host<br />

countries—China, India and Brazil—host over<br />

70 percent of approved <strong>CDM</strong> projects and will<br />

generate three-quarters of all CERs by 2012.<br />

Differentiation of Developing<br />

Country Eligibility<br />

The international negotiations include a highly<br />

contentious discussion of possible graduation<br />

of some non-Annex I Parties to a state of<br />

target- or action-based commitments. Arguing<br />

<strong>for</strong> differentiation in the August 2008 Accra<br />

5 Other approaches to REDD financing are also being discussed in the<br />

negotiations, <strong>including</strong> a market-linked system whereby a dedicated REDD<br />

trading mechanism is established and a non-market approach where<br />

a small proportion of international emission allowances would be sold<br />

to developed countries with the revenues going into a fund to support<br />

REDD ef<strong>for</strong>ts in developing countries.<br />

discussions, Australia noted that 45 developing<br />

countries have a GDP per capita higher than<br />

that of Ukraine which is an Annex I country—<br />

<strong>including</strong> South Korea, Qatar, Bahrain, Saudi<br />

Arabia, Singapore, Bahamas—suggesting that<br />

this be an indicator <strong>for</strong> differentiation (Third<br />

World Network, 2008b). Cosbey and Drexhage<br />

(2007) argue that there will be pressure <strong>for</strong><br />

major developing countries to take actions<br />

commensurate with their capacity, which could<br />

include an expansion of Kyoto’s simple two-tiered<br />

system. Most (but not all) developing nations, on<br />

the other hand, argue that the only differentiation<br />

under the Convention and the Bali Action Plan is<br />

the differentiated response between developed<br />

and developing countries under the principle<br />

of common but differentiated responsibilities,<br />

<strong>including</strong> the historical responsibilities of the<br />

developed countries <strong>for</strong> GHG emissions.<br />

Approaches that favour graduation of some<br />

non-Annex I countries will have perhaps the<br />

most interesting impacts on the function of any<br />

MMSD. An option would be to involve the major<br />

developing country Parties with targets in IET and<br />

JI-like mechanisms, perhaps providing incentives<br />

<strong>for</strong> developing country participation by allowing<br />

these countries to receive large amounts of surplus<br />

allowances. There could be a separate scaled-down<br />

version of the current <strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong> those countries<br />

without targets. There are disincentives (discussed<br />

below) <strong>for</strong> developing countries to pursue such a<br />

negotiated outcome, perhaps surmountable by<br />

the granting of large surplus allowances matched<br />

by tough Annex I targets.<br />

Development Dividend Implications<br />

Quality – With selective differentiation, the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> would probably become more oriented to<br />

development than mitigation, serving the needs<br />

Implications <strong>for</strong> the Development Dividend<br />

13<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


of lesser developed countries and comprising a<br />

portfolio of projects that achieve high development<br />

dividends.<br />

While the <strong>CDM</strong> is explicitly aimed at fostering<br />

sustainable development in the host countries,<br />

IET and JI have no such explicit aim. If the starting<br />

point is the need <strong>for</strong> an MMSD focused on both<br />

low-cost emissions and sustainable development,<br />

then one option would be to “green” AAUs in a<br />

development-friendly manner, or to amend the JI<br />

to include sustainable development requirements<br />

(i.e., the requirement <strong>for</strong> host country approval on<br />

sustainable development grounds). This could be<br />

made effective exclusively <strong>for</strong> developing country<br />

hosts, or more broadly <strong>for</strong> all host countries.<br />

On the other hand, it can be argued that<br />

JI implicitly includes an imperative to foster<br />

sustainable development, or at least to serve<br />

national interests according to some definition.<br />

If a JI project offered no development dividend,<br />

there would be no reason <strong>for</strong> a host country to<br />

allow it, given that any ERUs it produced would<br />

result in increases to the host’s emission reduction<br />

commitment. In fact, since some percentage of<br />

JI projects will inevitably be non-additional, the<br />

ancillary benefits of the project roster as a whole<br />

will have to be seen by the host to be sufficient<br />

to more than balance out the resulting effective<br />

increases in its assigned amount.<br />

One implication of a JI as a replacement <strong>for</strong> the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> is that such a regime would shift the burden<br />

<strong>for</strong> determining additionality away from the<br />

international level and toward the national (to<br />

the extent that the <strong>new</strong> mechanism functioned<br />

like Track 1 JI). That is, at the global level the JI<br />

mechanism does not allow <strong>for</strong> a net reduction in<br />

emission reduction commitments, so only the host<br />

state needs to be concerned about additionality.<br />

This would greatly simplify the international<br />

administrative machinery as compared to the <strong>CDM</strong>,<br />

but it might also result in inefficient duplication<br />

of similar ef<strong>for</strong>ts at each national level.<br />

Any regime that incorporated such a mechanism,<br />

of course, would have to account <strong>for</strong> the<br />

fundamental differences between this and<br />

the existing narrow <strong>CDM</strong>. From a developing<br />

country perspective, the existing <strong>CDM</strong> is a more<br />

or less unblemished good, bringing as it does a<br />

measure of development dividend without any<br />

attendant obligations. A JI-type mechanism that<br />

covered developing countries would still bring<br />

those sorts of benefits to host countries, but<br />

would take place in the context of host country<br />

obligations to reduce emissions, and would see all<br />

credits accruing to the investor’s home country,<br />

counting toward its reduction commitment. In<br />

effect, this requires the host country to give up<br />

low hanging fruit <strong>for</strong> the emissions reduction<br />

benefit of others. As such, developing countries<br />

would presumably need to be compensated in<br />

the design of the regime <strong>for</strong> losing the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

Quantity – A regime with selective differentiation<br />

means that the market will not experience the<br />

large volumes of credits as seen from the major<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> players. The major developing countries<br />

are by and far the main suppliers of CERs up to<br />

2012. If, <strong>for</strong> example, we removed China from the<br />

market, the number of projects in the current<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> pipeline would be reduced by 36 percent<br />

and the number of CERs by 2012 would drop<br />

fully by 54 percent (UNEP-Risoe Centre, 2008).<br />

This shortfall might be made up to some extent<br />

by broadening the scope of the <strong>CDM</strong>, and some<br />

developed countries may turn to ERUs or AAUs<br />

to meet compliance targets.<br />

14<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Regional distribution - Differentiation could<br />

impact on the regional and equitable distribution<br />

of projects. As countries graduate from the <strong>CDM</strong>,<br />

a greater share of the market will be open to LDCs.<br />

At present, regional distribution is very unequal<br />

with Latin America & the Caribbean and Asia &<br />

Pacific together accounting <strong>for</strong> over 95 percent<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong> projects and just under 95 percent of<br />

CERs. LDCs account <strong>for</strong> 28 projects in the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

pipeline—less than 1 percent of the projects<br />

and 1 percent of the CERs (UNEP-Risoe Centre,<br />

2008). Of course there is no guarantee that<br />

the funds that <strong>for</strong>merly flowed to large targets<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong> finance would actually be redirected to<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> in smaller countries. Investment tends to<br />

flow to the best available opportunities, and if the<br />

barriers to <strong>CDM</strong> investment in those countries<br />

are high enough, the market might simply shrink,<br />

rather than redistribute. In fact such an effect is<br />

practically guaranteed—the question is simply<br />

how significant it would be.<br />

Expanded <strong>CDM</strong><br />

An expanded <strong>CDM</strong> or a broader MMSD, which<br />

seeks to overcome perceived constraints of the<br />

current project-based approach by resort to policy<br />

or sectoral approaches, is also a topic in the post-<br />

2012 negotiations. The international discussions<br />

have narrowed the focus to include sectoral<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong> emission reductions below a baseline<br />

defined at a sectoral level; sectoral crediting<br />

of emissions reductions below a previously<br />

established no-lose target; and crediting on the<br />

basis of NAMA. While the existing architecture<br />

of the <strong>CDM</strong> would need to be modified to<br />

accommodate these proposals—technical issues<br />

such as baselines, monitoring and verification,<br />

and institutional issues such as working through<br />

the Executive Board could build on the current<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> framework.<br />

There is considerable interest in sectoral crediting<br />

mechanisms, but the various <strong>for</strong>mulations, to<br />

greater or lesser degrees, are subject to serious<br />

limitations. A primary difficulty is that there are<br />

not many sectors that would be amenable to<br />

sectoral crediting; it demands a small number<br />

of coordinated large emitters. For both sectoral<br />

and NAMA crediting mechanisms, baseline<br />

determination is plagued with fundamental<br />

The major developing countries are by and far<br />

the main suppliers of CERs up to 2012. If, <strong>for</strong><br />

example, we removed China from the market,<br />

the number of projects in the current <strong>CDM</strong><br />

pipeline would be reduced by 36 percent and<br />

the number of CERs by 2012 would drop fully<br />

by 54 percent (UNEP-Risoe Centre, 2008).<br />

difficulties, there is no easy way to determine<br />

additionality, and it is difficult to get around the<br />

problem of punishing first movers by crediting<br />

only those that moved after the implementation<br />

of a sectoral crediting or crediting on the basis<br />

of NAMA. Baron and Ellis (2006) argue that the<br />

difficulties of coordinating sectoral crediting<br />

mechanisms across a number of linked domestic<br />

and regional trading systems would probably<br />

prove insurmountable; and the same could hold<br />

true <strong>for</strong> credits based on NAMA.<br />

Development Dividend Implications<br />

Quality - The potential <strong>for</strong> an expanded <strong>CDM</strong><br />

to contribute to sustainable development is<br />

obvious. Sectoral <strong>CDM</strong> could be employed to<br />

exploit the win-win opportunities in sectors such<br />

as de<strong>for</strong>estation, energy and transportation, all<br />

Implications <strong>for</strong> the Development Dividend<br />

15<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


of which have enormous development linkages.<br />

Crediting on the basis of NAMA offers countries<br />

a more strategic and integrated mechanism,<br />

encouraging linkages with national development<br />

policies and encouraging project activity in<br />

such sectors as energy efficiency, re<strong>new</strong>able<br />

energy and transportation—sectors that tend to<br />

generate higher development dividends.<br />

Quantity - Sectoral <strong>CDM</strong> holds potential <strong>for</strong> an<br />

enormous amount of GHG mitigation, on a scale<br />

that far outpaces the current project-by-project<br />

<strong>for</strong>mulation of the <strong>CDM</strong> (Bosi and Ellis, 2005).<br />

Thus, an expanded <strong>CDM</strong> may give rise to the<br />

concerns discussed above in Section 2 about<br />

flooding the market <strong>for</strong> compliance units. One<br />

of the key benefits that many see in the prospect<br />

of an expanded <strong>CDM</strong> is its ability to deliver large<br />

quantities of GHG reductions as compared to the<br />

current bottom-up approach. But the question<br />

is whether the resulting flow of CERs would in<br />

fact find buyers, or to what extent the price of<br />

CERs would reach disastrous lows. Baumert and<br />

Winkler (2005) have argued that the expanded<br />

version of the <strong>CDM</strong> would vastly increase the<br />

potential <strong>for</strong> generating credits, perhaps well<br />

beyond what the market would bear in terms of<br />

demand. The analysis above cited projections of<br />

demand <strong>for</strong> all Kyoto compliance mechanisms—<br />

not just CERs—of between 1.6 and 2.5 GT by<br />

2012. On the supply side, very conservative<br />

estimates indicated potential <strong>for</strong> policy <strong>CDM</strong> to<br />

yield at least 3.6 GT of annual CO 2<br />

e reductions<br />

by 2030 (Cosbey, Murphy and Drexhage, 2007:<br />

14).<br />

An expanded <strong>CDM</strong> has clear potential to reduce<br />

GHG emissions at a higher order of magnitude<br />

than the narrow version. This may be good <strong>new</strong>s<br />

<strong>for</strong> buyers, but only up to a point. If the market<br />

becomes swamped it will crash, with values <strong>for</strong><br />

CERs coming in at well below what proponents<br />

projected, potentially leading to widespread<br />

abandonment of project-based initiatives. One<br />

clear implication <strong>for</strong> a regime that includes<br />

an expanded <strong>CDM</strong> is the need <strong>for</strong> ambitious<br />

reduction targets that will fuel demand <strong>for</strong> the<br />

additional CERs that may be brought on line,<br />

though the expanding voluntary market may pick<br />

up some of any excess supply.<br />

Regional distribution – Sectoral <strong>CDM</strong> would be<br />

likely to start in the more advanced developing<br />

nations, because they are more likely to have<br />

a large industrial base, and have worked with<br />

existing sectoral initiatives such as the Cement<br />

Sustainability Initiative. Crediting on the basis of<br />

NAMA would also likely favour the more advanced<br />

developing nations, continuing the pattern of<br />

uneven regional distribution of projects. There<br />

are proposals that recognize this imbalance, with<br />

South Korea suggesting that a share of proceeds<br />

from the revenue of NAMA credits be allocated<br />

to support LDCs and Small Island Developing<br />

States (Republic of Korea, 2008).<br />

Fund-based Mechanism<br />

Financing is an explicit part of the Bali Action<br />

Plan and the negotiations include discussion of<br />

the types of institutional innovation that might<br />

support the necessary financial transfers from<br />

developed to developing countries. . There could<br />

be potential <strong>for</strong> linking some of the transfers<br />

to specific sustainable development attributes<br />

by associating the support with a fund-based<br />

mechanism.<br />

The original proposal from Brazil that led to the<br />

creation of the <strong>CDM</strong> was <strong>for</strong> a clean development<br />

fund, endowed by Annex I countries, which would<br />

support sustainable development in developing<br />

countries in ways that also achieved mitigation.<br />

As well, Mexico (2008) recently proposed a<br />

16<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Green Fund that would support such activities,<br />

though the resulting emissions reductions would<br />

not be used to offset emissions in developed<br />

countries. A fund-based mechanism based on<br />

these conceptions is discussed here because<br />

it is unique among the options described; it<br />

can operate within and outside a regime of<br />

internationally agreed targets.<br />

A fund-based mechanism could have a scope<br />

similar to the <strong>CDM</strong>, and would consist of<br />

mandatory contributions from UNFCCC Parties,<br />

the nature and extent of the contributions being<br />

a matter of international negotiations. In the end<br />

there are a number of ways that contributions<br />

could be assessed. The Mexican proposal calls<br />

<strong>for</strong> basing contributions on an index composed<br />

of GHG emissions (present and historic, absolute<br />

and per-capita), GDP and population.<br />

This fund would then be used to purchase<br />

emission reduction credits from GHG-reducing<br />

projects, policies or programs in developing<br />

countries. If the Fund operated under a regime<br />

with targets, the credits involved could be used<br />

to retire obligations of the funders, assigned in<br />

proportion to contributions. If it operated under<br />

a regime without targets, it would be considered<br />

a straight funding mechanism, similar to the<br />

Mexican proposal, able to fulfill developed<br />

countries’ Article 4.3 UNFCCC obligations to<br />

cover the incremental costs of addressing climate<br />

change in developing countries. 6 In contrast to the<br />

“with targets” Fund, such a scheme would result<br />

in net global mitigation of GHG emissions.<br />

There are a number of ways in which the Fund<br />

could disperse its resources, but primary among<br />

the design considerations would be a desire to<br />

harness the ingenuity and energy of the private<br />

sector, as does the existing <strong>CDM</strong>. One possibility<br />

would be a reverse auction arrangement, whereby<br />

project proponents would commit to delivering<br />

credits <strong>for</strong> agreed prices, and would bid against<br />

each other in competition <strong>for</strong> contracts. Under<br />

this scenario, contracts would be awarded to the<br />

lowest bidder that satisfied the methodological<br />

requirements (such as additionality), and the<br />

bidding would stop when the budget tranche <strong>for</strong><br />

a particular time period had been exhausted. 7<br />

Inevitably there would be projects <strong>for</strong> which<br />

the terms of the contract were unfulfilled, <strong>for</strong><br />

example because the project failed to receive<br />

project funding. The unused funds from such<br />

projects could simply be rolled back into the<br />

next tranche of funding.<br />

Development Dividend Implications<br />

Quality – A fund-based mechanism could be<br />

structured to explicitly direct financial transfers<br />

to sustainable development priorities. There may<br />

need to be a specific definition <strong>for</strong> sustainable<br />

development under the fund, i.e., the project<br />

meets an agreed list of minimal sustainable<br />

development benefits or is ranked on a point<br />

system. A funding mechanism could also be<br />

combined with a more traditional type of MMSD,<br />

in a pairing that had the fund focusing more<br />

explicitly on sustainable development and the<br />

more traditional mechanism focusing on sheer<br />

volume.<br />

6 If the Fund operated in this mode, there is no reason why it could<br />

not welcome non-governmental “voluntary market” investors as well, in<br />

a scheme that could simultaneously give that market the credibility it<br />

needed, and provide important extra funding <strong>for</strong> mitigation and sustainable<br />

development in developing countries.<br />

7 One advantage to such a process is that it would eliminate some of<br />

the huge producer surplus generated by the current system. In a reverse<br />

auction it is highly unlikely, <strong>for</strong> example, that HFC projects with costs as<br />

low as US$1/tonne would fetch the kinds of prices they are currently<br />

fetching in the carbon market.<br />

Implications <strong>for</strong> the Development Dividend<br />

17<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Quantity – Could a fund supported entirely by<br />

governments foster the same volume of GHG<br />

reduction units as could a market mechanism,<br />

such as the current <strong>CDM</strong>, that relies extensively<br />

on private investment? While no hard data exists<br />

<strong>for</strong> the magnitude of <strong>CDM</strong> investment, UNFCCC<br />

(2007b) estimates that there was US$7 billion<br />

invested as a result of the <strong>CDM</strong> projects that were<br />

registered in 2006—a figure that is probably well<br />

below the capacity of a re<strong>for</strong>med <strong>CDM</strong> to deliver<br />

in the post-2012 context. To give an indication of<br />

the magnitude of that flow relative to the kind of<br />

flows made available by governments <strong>for</strong> the same<br />

sorts of purposes, note that the total funding<br />

<strong>for</strong> the most recent four-year replenishment<br />

<strong>for</strong> the Global Environment Facility averaged<br />

out to about US$0.8 billion per year. Of this,<br />

it disburses about US$250 million per year on<br />

mitigation-related activities. Another standard<br />

<strong>for</strong> comparison is provided by the recently<br />

established and highly publicized World Bank<br />

Climate Investment Funds (part of which will be<br />

devoted to adaptation funding), which combined<br />

are targeted to reach US$5 billion over 3 years,<br />

or US$1.7 billion per annum.<br />

In light of these standards, there might be cause<br />

<strong>for</strong> concern in relying only on a governmentsupported<br />

fund to support mitigation ef<strong>for</strong>ts. It<br />

would certainly be a challenge to raise the kind<br />

of money needed to even replace the private<br />

sector investment that currently goes into the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>, much less the potential investment under<br />

a re<strong>for</strong>med and broadened <strong>CDM</strong>. The recent<br />

economic downturn suggests that it may be a<br />

difficult time to generate significant <strong>new</strong> funds<br />

in many developed countries, particularly if<br />

these funds are perceived to support investment<br />

in major developing countries, such as China,<br />

with its rising economic power.<br />

Regional distribution – A fund-based mechanism<br />

may be the most suited to equitable regional<br />

distribution, whereby a portion of the funding<br />

can be allocated to LDCs. The percentage of<br />

funding allocated to poorer countries would<br />

need to be carefully considered. While it may<br />

be true that the major developing countries<br />

account <strong>for</strong> the majority of <strong>CDM</strong> investment, it is<br />

also true that they also account <strong>for</strong> the majority<br />

of population, GDP and energy use among<br />

developing countries. A weighted distribution<br />

of funding using, <strong>for</strong> example, an average of<br />

population-deflated and GDP-deflated figures,<br />

could help to determine an equitable distribution<br />

of funds. 8 Of course, capacity building to set up<br />

an enabling environment <strong>for</strong> climate mitigation<br />

investment will be needed in many LDCs.<br />

Conclusion<br />

There is uncertainty about the long-term<br />

nature of the carbon market, but there is broad<br />

consensus in the international talks on a post-<br />

2012 climate change regime on the need <strong>for</strong><br />

some perpetuation of the <strong>CDM</strong>—a market<br />

mechanism <strong>for</strong> sustainable development.<br />

Emissions trading will likely <strong>for</strong>m an important<br />

cornerstone of future action on climate change,<br />

and the <strong>CDM</strong> or other MMSD with a strong focus<br />

on cost efficiency and flexibility is important<br />

to businesses seeking credits <strong>for</strong> compliance.<br />

And such a mechanism can help developing<br />

countries encourage sustainable development<br />

and contribute to the objective of the UNFCCC<br />

to reduce GHG emissions, consistent with the<br />

goal of Article 12 of the Kyoto Protocol.<br />

The structure of the post-2012 regime will have<br />

a strong influence on the development dividend.<br />

8 See Cosbey (2006: 26-29) <strong>for</strong> a discussion of weighted regional<br />

distribution of <strong>CDM</strong> projects.<br />

18<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


If developed country concerns of access to<br />

reasonably priced quality credits are met and<br />

there is meaningful participation by developing<br />

countries, especially the large emitters of China,<br />

India and Brazil, there likely will be high demand<br />

<strong>for</strong> these credits. 9 If these concerns are not met<br />

and the sustainable development benefits of<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> projects are questionable, there could be<br />

strong political pressure in developed countries<br />

to undertake domestic emission reductions,<br />

weakening the market <strong>for</strong> credits under the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

in the current pipeline are from such countries.<br />

There are, however, options to increase the<br />

supply of CERs, such as broadening the scope<br />

of and expanding the <strong>CDM</strong>. Under such regimes<br />

the main consideration would be the volume of<br />

credits potentially issued and the subsequent<br />

impacts on the carbon market. Absent ambitious<br />

Annex I targets, the high volumes generated<br />

might have the potential to increase the supply<br />

of CERs to the point where the market might be<br />

swamped. In such a case there may be potential<br />

Four possible post-2012 regime options and the<br />

implications <strong>for</strong> the development dividend within<br />

each approach have been examined in this paper.<br />

As noted in Table 1, a fund-based mechanism<br />

is best able to address the issues of quality<br />

and regional distribution because it can be<br />

structured to explicitly direct financial transfers<br />

to sustainable development priorities and LDCs.<br />

But it will be challenging, and likely impossible,<br />

to get agreement on a level of funding similar to<br />

that expected to flow through an MMSD. A regime<br />

with graduation criteria could create a greater<br />

market share <strong>for</strong> LDCs, but there is no guarantee<br />

that investment will flow to these countries. A<br />

wider scope <strong>for</strong> LULUCF projects also could<br />

benefit LDCs, but considerable capacity building<br />

would likely be needed to create conditions to<br />

attract investment. LULUCF projects also offer<br />

considerable promise <strong>for</strong> generating SD benefits;<br />

as does expanding the <strong>CDM</strong> to include crediting<br />

on the basis of NAMA and sectoral <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

In regard to quantity, if the more advanced<br />

developing nations take on targets, the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

market will see massive reduction in volumes<br />

supplied since the majority of projects and CERs<br />

Key elements being explored include<br />

broadening the scope of the <strong>CDM</strong> to include<br />

other activities (land use, land-use change<br />

and <strong>for</strong>estry (LULUCF), carbon capture and<br />

storage (CCS) and nuclear); and expanding<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> to include sectoral <strong>CDM</strong>, sectoral<br />

crediting of emission reductions below a<br />

previously established no-lose target, and/<br />

or crediting on the basis of nationally<br />

appropriate mitigation actions (NAMA).<br />

<strong>for</strong> CERs to sell on the as-yet-nascent voluntary<br />

market. Without increases in demand, prices<br />

might hit destructively low levels under some of<br />

the broadened and expanded <strong>CDM</strong> scenarios.<br />

It is important to note that the more attractive<br />

an MMSD becomes in a post-2012 regime,<br />

other things being equal, the less incentive any<br />

developing country has to take on targets that<br />

entail lost access to the mechanism. 10 If the post-<br />

9 Of course, as noted above, if “meaningful participation” takes the<br />

<strong>for</strong>m of developing country targets, the <strong>CDM</strong> as it is currently configured<br />

will not operate.<br />

10 The assumption of other things being equal is important. It is of<br />

course possible to imagine a regime such as those described in Section 3,<br />

involving targets <strong>for</strong> all, emissions trading, with tough enough developed<br />

Implications <strong>for</strong> the Development Dividend<br />

19<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Table 1: Development dividend impacts of post-2012 approaches under discussion in the international negotiations<br />

Approach<br />

Regime Characteristics<br />

Development Dividend Implications<br />

Quality Quantity Regional Distribution<br />

Targets with<br />

Emission reduction<br />

LULUCF projects offer<br />

Broadening scope<br />

Wider scope of LU-<br />

flexibility<br />

targets<br />

considerable SD benefits<br />

could unlock huge<br />

LUCF projects could<br />

mechanisms –<br />

Differentiation of<br />

Projects with question-<br />

potential supply of<br />

encourage broader<br />

broadening the<br />

those with targets<br />

able SD benefits could<br />

credits, perhaps be-<br />

participation, <strong>including</strong><br />

scope<br />

and those without<br />

be included (e.g., CCS,<br />

yond what the market<br />

LDCs, CCS and nu-<br />

nuclear)<br />

can bear in the absence<br />

clear projects likely to<br />

of ambitious targets in<br />

benefit more advanced<br />

developedcountries<br />

develoing nations<br />

Differentiation<br />

Emission reduction<br />

IET and JI have no aim to<br />

Market will not experi-<br />

Greater share of market<br />

of develop-<br />

targets<br />

foster SD; options are to<br />

ence large volume of<br />

open to LDCs, but no<br />

ing country<br />

Differentiation of<br />

green AAUs or amend JI<br />

CERs (as the main sup-<br />

guarantee that <strong>CDM</strong><br />

eligibility<br />

those with targets<br />

to include SD require-<br />

pliers of credits up to<br />

funds will be redirected<br />

and those without<br />

ments<br />

2012—more advanced<br />

to these countries<br />

Graduation criteria<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> could be more<br />

developing countries—<br />

<strong>for</strong> developing<br />

oriented to serving the<br />

will graduate<br />

countries<br />

SD needs of lesser developed<br />

countries<br />

Expanded <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Emission reduction<br />

Sectoral <strong>CDM</strong> could<br />

Vastly increased poten-<br />

Sectoral <strong>CDM</strong> and<br />

targets<br />

exploit development<br />

tial <strong>for</strong> CERs, perhaps<br />

crediting on the basis<br />

Differentiation of<br />

linkages in such sectors<br />

beyond what the<br />

of NAMA would benefit<br />

those with targets<br />

as de<strong>for</strong>estation, energy<br />

market can bear in the<br />

the more advanced<br />

and those without<br />

and transportation<br />

absence of ambitious<br />

developing countries,<br />

Crediting on the basis<br />

targets in developed<br />

continuing the pattern<br />

of NAMA offers linkages<br />

countries<br />

of uneven regional<br />

with national develop-<br />

distribution<br />

ment priorities and activities<br />

in high SD areas.<br />

Fund-based<br />

Could operate<br />

Fund structure could<br />

Challenging <strong>for</strong> a<br />

Most suited to equita-<br />

mechanism<br />

within and outside<br />

explicitly direct financial<br />

government-supported<br />

ble regional distribu-<br />

a regime of inter-<br />

transfers to SD priorities<br />

fund to replace the<br />

tion, whereby a portion<br />

nationally agreed<br />

level of private sector<br />

of funding can be<br />

targets<br />

investment that goes<br />

allocated to LDCs<br />

into the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

20<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


2012 regime includes a radically expanded MMSD<br />

that covers sectoral and NAMA initiatives, it is<br />

offering governments the opportunity to fund<br />

a variety of policies and programmes that they<br />

might have as current priorities, but <strong>for</strong> which<br />

they lack the requisite resources. This clearly<br />

counts as a more attractive MMSD.<br />

Given the broad desire <strong>for</strong> some sort of MMSD<br />

in the post-2012 regime, it is important to<br />

understand the significance of the various<br />

possible regimes on the shape of an MMSD. This<br />

paper takes a first step in this direction, providing<br />

policy makers with a deeper understanding of<br />

the development dividend implications (quality,<br />

quantity and regional distribution) of various<br />

MMSDs.<br />

Deborah Murphy works with the International Institute <strong>for</strong><br />

Sustainable Development (IISD) with the Climate Change and<br />

Energy Program. Her work on climate change is focused on<br />

market mechanisms, technology, the post-2012 climate change<br />

regime, governance, and more fully exploring the links between<br />

climate change and sectoral policies.<br />

Contact: dmurphy@iisd.ca<br />

Aaron Cosbey manages the Trade and Climate Change<br />

Programme with the International Institute <strong>for</strong> Sustainable<br />

Development (IISD). He is a development economist and has<br />

served as advisor and consultant to a number of governments<br />

and intergovernmental organizations.<br />

Contact: acosbey@iisd.ca<br />

John Drexhage is Director of the Climate Change and<br />

Energy Program of the International Institute <strong>for</strong> Sustainable<br />

Development (IISD). He has extensive experience in climate<br />

change and energy, <strong>including</strong> periods as a domestic advisor and<br />

international negotiator on climate change, followed by work as<br />

an expert analyst and manager <strong>for</strong> IISD.<br />

Contact: jdrexhage@iisd.ca<br />

References<br />

Baron, R. and J. Ellis, 2006. Sectoral Crediting <strong>Mechanisms</strong> <strong>for</strong> Greenhouse<br />

Gas Mitigation: Institutional and Operational Issues. OECD<br />

Environment Directorate and International Energy Agency. COM/ENV/<br />

EPOC/IEA/SLT(2006)4.<br />

Baumert, K. A. and H. Winkler, 2005. “Sustainable Development Policies<br />

and Measures and International Climate Agreements.” In Bradley, Rob,<br />

Kevin A. Baumert et al., Growing in the Greenhouse: Protecting the Climate<br />

by Putting Development First. Washington, D. C.: World Resources<br />

Institute. pp. 15-23.<br />

Bosi, M. and J. Ellis, 2005. Exploring Options <strong>for</strong> “Sectoral Crediting<br />

<strong>Mechanisms</strong>.” Paris: OECD Environment Directorate and International<br />

Energy Agency. COM/ENV/EPOC/IEA/SLT(2005)1.<br />

Cosbey, A., 2006. “Defining and Measuring the Development Dividend.”<br />

Making Development Work in the <strong>CDM</strong>: Phase II of the Development<br />

Dividend Project. pre-publication version. Winnipeg: IISD.<br />

Cosbey, A. and J. Drexhage, 2007. Advancing Development Goals in a<br />

Sustainable Manner: Options and Implications <strong>for</strong> Post-2012 International<br />

Climate Change Ef<strong>for</strong>ts. A Way Forward Working Paper #1. Winnipeg:<br />

International Institute <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development.<br />

Cosbey, A., D. Murphy and J. Drexhage, 2007. Market <strong>Mechanisms</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

Sustainable Development: How do they fit in the various post-2012<br />

climate ef<strong>for</strong>ts? Winnipeg: IISD.<br />

Cosbey, A., J. Parry, J. Borwen, Y.D. Babu, P. Bhandari, J. Drexhage and D,<br />

Murphy, 2005. Realizing the Development Dividend: Making the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Work in Developing Countries. Winnipeg: IISD.<br />

Mexico, 2008. Submission by Mexico. Submission to the third session of<br />

the Ad Hoc Working Group on Long-term Cooperative Action under the<br />

Convention. .<br />

Nepstad, D., B. Soares-Filho, F. Merry, P. Moutinho, M. Bowman, S.<br />

Schwartzman, O. Almeida and S. Rivero, 2007. The Costs and Benefits of<br />

Reducing Carbon Emissions from De<strong>for</strong>estation and Forest Degradation in<br />

the Brazilian Amazon. Falmouth, MA: Woods Hole Research Center.<br />

Republic of Korea, 2008. Market-based Post-2012 Climate Regime: Carbon<br />

Credit <strong>for</strong> NAMAs. Submission to the third session of the Ad Hoc<br />

Working Group on Long-term Cooperative Action under the Convention.<br />

.<br />

Schlamadinger, B., 2007. “Post-2012 eligibility of land-use and bioenergy<br />

activities in the <strong>CDM</strong>.” Presented at Annex I Expert Group Seminar with<br />

Developing Countries: Working Together to Respond to Climate Change,<br />

19-20 March 2007, Paris.<br />

Third World Network, 2008a. “Accept ambitious reduction targets, Annex<br />

I told at Kyoto group meeting.” TWN Accra News Update 2. 22 August.<br />

Penang, Malaysia: Third World Network.<br />

Third World Network, 2008b. “North floats idea of <strong>new</strong> climate regime,<br />

South warns this threatens Copenhagen outcome.” TWN Accra News<br />

Update 9. Penang, Malaysia: Third World Network.<br />

UNEP-Risoe Centre, 2008. <strong>CDM</strong> Pipeline Overview. September 1 st , 2008<br />

version. .<br />

UNFCCC, 2007a. Bali Action Plan. Decision adopted by COP 13 and<br />

CMP 3. December 2007. .<br />

UNFCCC, 2007b. Investment and financial flows to address climate change.<br />

Bonn: UNFCCC<br />

UNFCCC, 2008. Emissions trading and the project-based mechanisms:<br />

Draft conclusions proposed by the Chair. Ad Hoc Working Group on<br />

Further Commitments <strong>for</strong> Annex I Parties under the Kyoto Protocol. Sixth<br />

Session, Accra, 21-27 August 2008 and Poznan, 1-10 December 2008.<br />

FCCC/KP/AWG/2008/L.12, 27 August.<br />

Wara, M. and D. Victor, 2008. A Realistic Policy on International Carbon<br />

Offsets. PESD Working Paper #74. Palo Alto, CA: Stan<strong>for</strong>d University.<br />

country targets and generous enough allowances <strong>for</strong> developing countries<br />

to overcome the disadvantage of losing the <strong>CDM</strong> as a mechanism.<br />

Implications <strong>for</strong> the Development Dividend<br />

21<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


22<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Branca Americano<br />

Designated National<br />

Authority (DNA) Brazil<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> in Brazil:<br />

Towards Structural Change<br />

<strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development<br />

in Some Sectors<br />

Abstract<br />

In this article, experience with <strong>CDM</strong> in Brazil<br />

is analysed in terms of its capacity to promote<br />

long-term benefits in the direction of a lowcarbon<br />

economy. For this purpose, a set of 280<br />

projects, <strong>including</strong> projects at the validation<br />

stage and approved projects, are categorized<br />

according to project type and analysed using<br />

two criteria: the number of projects in each<br />

category, and emission reductions. For each of<br />

the categories – landfill gas, N 2<br />

O from industry,<br />

hydro-power plants, biogas from pig farms and<br />

bagasse – the sector and/or technology is briefly<br />

described and how the <strong>CDM</strong> project activity has<br />

impacted and trans<strong>for</strong>med the sector analysed.<br />

As everyone knows <strong>CDM</strong> is a mechanism with very<br />

particular characteristics. It has an important<br />

economic basis, and the intention is to optimize<br />

resource allocation and minimize costs <strong>for</strong> emission<br />

reductions while contributing to the sustainable<br />

development of host countries. Nevertheless the<br />

mechanism as it is in real life is the result of hard<br />

negotiations and a possible consensus among 189<br />

Parties. Its final design is not completely rational<br />

or optimized, and many people who did not follow<br />

the negotiations have difficulties in understanding<br />

some of its characteristics.<br />

The two main concepts on which the mechanism<br />

is based are the concepts of additionality and its<br />

contribution to sustainable development. Both<br />

concepts are as complex as the mechanism itself.<br />

Sustainable development is up to each country to<br />

define and so is not objective or comparable as a<br />

concept. Additionality is also a difficult concept<br />

23<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


ecause of the underlying notion of a baseline.<br />

It is difficult to establish without a doubt what is<br />

the baseline scenario and to what extent the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

makes the difference when deciding to pursue a<br />

particular project activity. It is also difficult to<br />

determine to what extent the <strong>CDM</strong>, which most<br />

of the time makes only a marginal contribution,<br />

has a definitive role in pushing the balance in the<br />

direction of implementing the project activity.<br />

Nevertheless it is unquestionable that the <strong>CDM</strong> is<br />

a success and has introduced structural changes<br />

in some sectors in some countries.<br />

In this article I will analyse the <strong>CDM</strong> in Brazil.<br />

First, I will discuss the concept of sustainable<br />

development in the Brazilian context. Then I will<br />

analyse the evolution of the <strong>CDM</strong> in the country<br />

since the beginning of 2004, <strong>including</strong> projects<br />

that are in the pipeline awaiting validation.<br />

Then I will analyse some of the main types of<br />

projects to assess how they have changed their<br />

own sectors and how they have contributed to<br />

sustainable development in some aspects. The<br />

analysis is based on my experience of working in<br />

the executive secretariat of the Brazilian DNA, as<br />

well as on interviews with project developers and<br />

sectoral stakeholders.<br />

Sustainable Development in Brazil<br />

The Brazilian DNA is the Interministerial Comission<br />

on Climate Change (CIMGC) consisting of 11<br />

Ministries which meet once every second month<br />

to analyse projects and assess its contribution<br />

to sustainable development. Project proponents<br />

have to prepare a document, known as “Annex<br />

III”, in which the contribution of the project<br />

activity under five different aspects or headings<br />

must be explained. These five headings are: 1)<br />

contribution to local environmental sustainability;<br />

2) contribution to the improvement of labour<br />

conditions and net job creation; 3) contribution<br />

to the distribution of income; 4) contribution to<br />

training and technological development; and 5)<br />

contribution to regional integration and linkages<br />

with other sectors. There is no threshold <strong>for</strong> any<br />

of these five aspects or headings, nor any kind<br />

of indicator <strong>for</strong> any of them, nor any measure<br />

<strong>for</strong> all the aspects of sustainable development.<br />

The DNA takes into account the project itself<br />

based on the document, which explains the<br />

contribution to sustainable development (Annex<br />

III) and takes into consideration the whole<br />

picture. In many cases the CIMGC requests<br />

additional in<strong>for</strong>mation and clarification about<br />

the contribution envisaged to some of the<br />

sustainable development aspects described by<br />

the project proponent. The purpose is to make<br />

clear in the document the aims of the project<br />

proponents, who must make Annex III available<br />

to local stakeholders during consultation in the<br />

validation period. The document also remains on<br />

the Brazilian <strong>CDM</strong> homepage after the project<br />

has been registered. Making Annex III public,<br />

with a clear statement of how the project activity<br />

contributes to sustainable development, to some<br />

extent constrains the project proponents to<br />

comply with its promises. As it is well known, the<br />

letter of approval (LoA) is requested only once,<br />

at the moment of registration of the project<br />

activity. At this time, the host country issues a<br />

LoA stating that the project contributes to the<br />

sustainable development, though most often<br />

based on projects that are not yet in place, so that<br />

many of the aspects cannot be checked be<strong>for</strong>e<br />

registration. They consist of promises such as<br />

job creation, benefits <strong>for</strong> local communities,<br />

etc. However, there is no monitoring of the<br />

contribution to sustainable development. The<br />

control that the DNA has after issuance of the<br />

LoA is very limited. If the project does not comply<br />

with the country legislation, it is very easy to stop<br />

the activity using domestic law. However, if other<br />

aspects, like the number of <strong>new</strong> jobs created, are<br />

24<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


not in place as promised in Annex III, nothing<br />

can be done about it. In this regard, having<br />

Annex III publicly available and associated with<br />

the PDD in the Brazilian homepage is one way to<br />

ensure that promises are kept. It is important to<br />

mention that Parties can always request a review<br />

of projects at the moment of the registration<br />

and issuance of CERs if they wish. In addition,<br />

Brazil has the ability to cancel and/or revoke the<br />

LoA. This possibility is based on the fact that the<br />

LoA is an administrative act and hence can be<br />

cancelled or revoked. Article 2 of Resolution 4<br />

states that if, after the issuance of the LoA, <strong>new</strong><br />

in<strong>for</strong>mation comes to light providing evidence of<br />

illegal acts or acts contrary to the public interest,<br />

the Commission may cancel or revoke the LoA,<br />

provided all procedures <strong>for</strong> the exercise of the<br />

right of defence are followed. This ultimate<br />

resource can be used in very special cases. The<br />

idea is not to use it as a common procedure,<br />

i.e. as an administrative procedure, but rather<br />

as a political one in extreme situations.<br />

Besides these aspects of sustainable development<br />

adopted by the Brazilian DNA, this<br />

paper will consider another aspect, namely<br />

the capacity to promote long-term benefits in the<br />

direction of a low-carbon economy. The idea is to<br />

assess to what extent a type of project introduces<br />

long-term benefits to sustainable development<br />

beyond those of each individual project. In this<br />

paper I will elaborate on the ability of a type of<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project to introduce structural changes, that<br />

is, to promote clean and re<strong>new</strong>able technologies<br />

which point clearly to decarbonization of the<br />

production and consumption patterns on a<br />

sustainable and long-term basis.<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> projects in Brazil<br />

Brazil was once a pioneer in the <strong>CDM</strong>. The<br />

country was the first to have its methodology<br />

approved and the second to register a project,<br />

and <strong>for</strong> some years it was leading all the indicators<br />

<strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> projects. It is evident that, due to Brazil<br />

having a very low carbon-intensive energy matrix,<br />

India and China immediately took the lead in<br />

the process. Nevertheless Brazil still has a high<br />

potential <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> projects. The main comparative<br />

advantage is that we have an important<br />

institutional structure <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong> already in<br />

place: project developers, financing institutions,<br />

DOEs and DNA with great experience. This is an<br />

important distinguishing feature compared to<br />

However, there is no monitoring of the<br />

contribution to sustainable development.<br />

The control that the DNA has after<br />

issuance of the LoA is very limited.<br />

other countries because it allows stakeholders<br />

to identity <strong>CDM</strong> opportunities in the country.<br />

Currently many changes can be identified in the<br />

profile of <strong>CDM</strong> in Brazil. The main objective of<br />

this article is to identify what kinds of projects<br />

have contributed to structural changes in some<br />

sectors and how.<br />

To assess evolution over time, projects are<br />

identified by the starting date of comments. This<br />

mode of reference was chosen because it allows<br />

a comparison of all projects in the pipeline,<br />

<strong>including</strong> those which are not yet registered.<br />

Projects which were rejected were excluded from<br />

the analysis. The database used comes from the<br />

Towards Structural Change <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development in Some Sectors<br />

25<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


pipeline produced by Jørgen Fenhann, UNEP<br />

Risø Centre, version dated 11 June 2008. Thus<br />

the 2008 figures cover less than six months.<br />

The assembly taken into account in this analysis<br />

considers 280 project activities with expected<br />

reductions of 176,987 ktCO2 until 2012. In terms<br />

of power, installed capacity is 5958 MW. Many<br />

different types of project have been implemented<br />

since 2004, but it is possible to identify types<br />

of project that predominate in terms of both<br />

quantity and emissions reductions. The following<br />

table brings together the main types of project<br />

that have been implemented in Brazil.<br />

After identifying the cluster of projects that are<br />

significant in terms of number and emissions<br />

reductions, the project categories will be analysed<br />

and attempts made to identify their contribution<br />

to sustainable development. One particular<br />

concern is the contribution to changing the<br />

carbon intensity of a sector.<br />

Landfill gas project activities<br />

The situation in the country regarding the<br />

disposal of solid waste is very precarious. From<br />

a total of 228,413 tonnes of solid waste collected<br />

daily in Brazil in 2000, only 36% ended up in a<br />

sanitary landfill.1 Almost the same quantity goes<br />

to controlled landfill sites, and the remaining<br />

solid waste is deposited in open dumps. A very<br />

small proportion goes to other destinations such<br />

as composting plants and incineration. There<br />

is no legislation to en<strong>for</strong>ce the burning off of<br />

the biogas in the landfill. The practice is only to<br />

combust <strong>for</strong> security reasons to avoid accidental<br />

explosions and sometimes to reduce offensive<br />

smells.<br />

1 IBGE statistics http://www.ibge.gov.br/home/estatistica/populacao/<br />

condicaodevida/pnsb/lixo_coletado/lixo_coletado110.shtm<br />

Figure 1 – Cluster of Projects Analysed<br />

26<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


This kind of project activity captures the landfill<br />

gas and flares it, sometimes producing electricity<br />

and/or heat. Some other uses are possible, <strong>for</strong><br />

example, a <strong>new</strong> project in the pipeline proposes<br />

to use the biogas as an input to an industrial<br />

plant to produce re<strong>new</strong>able methanol.<br />

In general, the contribution of such projects<br />

is very clear in terms of local environmental<br />

sustainability and improvements in labour<br />

conditions. The situation of open dumps is<br />

precarious regarding the environmental aspects<br />

(air and water quality) and labour aspects. It is<br />

also clear that these projects introduce both <strong>new</strong><br />

technologies and <strong>new</strong> practices and mentalities<br />

into the waste sector. For the first time, solid<br />

waste, which is considered a big problem <strong>for</strong><br />

municipalities, is seen as a possible source of<br />

revenue. It is interesting to note that a lawsuit<br />

has been introduced questioning the right of<br />

exploration of some sanitary landfills. The waste,<br />

which was seen as an ambient liability, is now<br />

considered an additional financial resource,<br />

which stakeholders are disputing the right to<br />

explore. For the moment this source of revenue<br />

is completely dependent on CERs, but other uses<br />

such as energy generation are being explored<br />

and in the future may become sustainable. The<br />

possibility of managing landfills as an economic<br />

resource independent of <strong>CDM</strong> is not <strong>for</strong>eseen at<br />

the moment.<br />

The 28 landfill gas projects in Brazil, which<br />

represent 11% of the project activities in the<br />

pipeline, will contribute 30% of expected CERs<br />

until 2012. It is interesting to note that the first<br />

five projects approved in Brazil were landfill gas<br />

projects. The methodology is well established, and<br />

since the end of 2004, ACM0001 has been used<br />

in most projects. This stability and continuity<br />

in methodology has an important comparative<br />

advantage regarding other types of project.<br />

On the other hand, only towns with significant<br />

populations may have landfills big enough to<br />

justify a <strong>CDM</strong> project activity. In general, project<br />

proponents set the minimum population size of<br />

a region with a landfill <strong>for</strong> a <strong>CDM</strong> project at over<br />

100,000 inhabitants. The design of traditional<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> methodologies is highly adapted to this<br />

kind of project, which has a great potential to<br />

develop <strong>CDM</strong> projects in all big landfill sites<br />

in Brazil. Many municipalities are interested<br />

in developing <strong>CDM</strong> projects to construct and<br />

explore landfills, with the prospect of creating a<br />

sanitary revolution in urban areas. The Ministry<br />

of the Cities has structured a pilot programme to<br />

construct landfills which have not yet succeeded<br />

in creating incentives <strong>for</strong> municipalities with a<br />

total population of more than 180,000 residents.<br />

One problem identified <strong>for</strong> this kind of project<br />

is that it is very sensible from the political<br />

point of view, as it involves different political<br />

interests. Possible further improvements would<br />

be not to flare the biogas but always to generate<br />

electricity, heat or any other possible use of it.<br />

An important barrier to be overcome is the size<br />

limit on landfills. A <strong>new</strong> stage to be reached is<br />

to extend the collection and use of biogas to<br />

smaller landfills, which could be achieved with<br />

programmatic <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

N 2<br />

O Projects<br />

These projects are not important in terms of<br />

number (five projects, one adipic acid and four<br />

nitric acid). Nevertheless they are important in<br />

terms of emission reductions (21%) because of<br />

the high GWP of the N 2<br />

O, namely 3102 <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong><br />

purposes. It also has limited possibilities <strong>for</strong><br />

expansion because of the limited number of plants<br />

in the country. The great benefit of this kind of<br />

2 GWP values from the IPCC Second Assessment Report (SAR) <strong>for</strong><br />

1995 are the ones adopted in the Kyoto Protocol.<br />

CER Pricing: Legal Influences<br />

27<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


project is in terms of its emissions reductions.<br />

The benefits in term of sustainable development<br />

are limited. Many of these projects state in<br />

“Annex III”, describing the contribution of the<br />

project activity to sustainable development, that<br />

they will use some of the financial benefits from<br />

the CERs <strong>for</strong> environmental and social projects<br />

within the region of the plant. The contribution<br />

in terms of structural changes is limited, and <strong>for</strong><br />

that reason it will not be analysed in the context<br />

of this article.<br />

Hydro-power plants<br />

Installed capacity in Brazil is more than 100 GW.<br />

Of this total, 76% comes from hydropower plants<br />

and only 2% from small hydropower plants.3 The<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> was a great incentive <strong>for</strong> this kind of project.<br />

Sixty-one small hydropower plants proposed have<br />

been as <strong>CDM</strong> projects in Brazil, representing<br />

22% of the project activities in the pipeline.<br />

These projects are contributing with 14% of the<br />

expected CERs until 2012. The contribution in<br />

terms of sustainable development is evident.<br />

The government is also concerned to encourage<br />

this type of project. The incentive programme<br />

<strong>for</strong> re<strong>new</strong>able sources of electricity (PROINFA)<br />

was first established in 2002 and revised in<br />

2004. Its objective is to provide incentives <strong>for</strong><br />

wind, biomass and small hydropower plants. The<br />

Development Bank (BNDES) may finance 70% of<br />

the investment, and Eletrobrás guarantees prices<br />

<strong>for</strong> some of the energy. The additionality of<br />

projects that benefit from the PROINFA incentive<br />

is not questioned, as this type of incentive,<br />

defined as policy type –E4, is considered in the<br />

baseline scenario. In the Proinfa decree, which<br />

3 Under Brazilian regulations, small hydropower plants are those with<br />

between 1 MW and 30MW of installed capacity.<br />

4 EB16 Annex 3 / Clarifications on the treatment of national and/or<br />

sectoral policies and regulations (paragraph 45 (e) of the <strong>CDM</strong> Modalities<br />

and Procedures) in determining a baseline scenario.<br />

makes reference to its voluntary contribution to<br />

the mitigation of climate change, Eletrobrás is<br />

appointed the owner of possible CERs generated<br />

by <strong>CDM</strong> projects using PROINFA incentives.<br />

However, many projects which benefit from<br />

PROINFA were developed by private initiative<br />

without the participation of Eletrobrás as<br />

project participant. This has generated different<br />

interpretations regarding entitlement to CERs,<br />

and many project proponents are awaiting a<br />

resolution of this problem be<strong>for</strong>e proposing<br />

<strong>new</strong> activities in this sector. At present, projects<br />

that might apply <strong>for</strong> Proinfa incentives are going<br />

instead <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong> exclusively.<br />

Emissions reductions from this type of project are<br />

real and measurable and contribute in the long<br />

term to reducing emissions because the life-time<br />

of a small hydropower project is 50 to 70 years. On<br />

the other hand, it is very difficult to assess to what<br />

extent the <strong>CDM</strong> was really the main factor driving<br />

the investment decision. This kind of investment<br />

has a high risk, and all incentives to reduce<br />

the risk are welcome. <strong>CDM</strong> is just one of them.<br />

How decisive the <strong>CDM</strong> is in making investment<br />

decisions in particular projects is also difficult to<br />

assess. The additionality tool is not sufficient to<br />

assess the complexity of this kind of investment<br />

decision. Even if it is difficult to assure with total<br />

certainty that one small hydropower plant would<br />

not have been constructed without <strong>CDM</strong>, there<br />

is a consensus that <strong>CDM</strong> had a positive impact<br />

in terms of increasing the number of investors<br />

interested in small hydropower plants.<br />

Biogas: pigs<br />

These projects consist, in general, in changing the<br />

treatment of animal waste management systems<br />

(AWMS). Currently, pig waste is flushed from the<br />

barns and treated through sequential anaerobic<br />

lagoon management. The project activity consists<br />

28<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


of covering the lagoons, collecting the biogas and<br />

combusting it. Some of these projects use the<br />

biogas to produce heat and/or electricity. This<br />

has many evident local environmental benefits<br />

because it reduces the risk of underground water<br />

contamination, bad smells and the pathogenic<br />

vectors associated with animal manure. It also<br />

improves the quality of pig manure as fertilizer. In<br />

general people who live in the area and work on<br />

the farms are very positive about the project and<br />

very cooperative with regard to the management<br />

of the system.<br />

The additionality of this kind of project is very<br />

clear. In most of them, the only monetary benefit<br />

comes from the CERs. There are 47 projects in this<br />

category in Brazil, but most of them are bundles<br />

of small-scale projects and have already covered<br />

more than 250 farms. In terms of emissions<br />

reductions, these projects will contribute 8% of<br />

the expected CERs until 2012.<br />

Even though this kind of project is very positive<br />

and represents tremendous opportunities in<br />

Brazil, it has faced many problems. It was first<br />

developed using methodology AM0016, which<br />

was put on hold at the 24 EB meeting. This<br />

methodology did not include monitoring of<br />

flares, and estimates of emissions reductions<br />

were not conservative. When it was replaced by<br />

ACM0010, many projects could not adapt because<br />

of the higher costs associated with the high risk<br />

of the activity, which reduced their economic<br />

viability. Projects using methodology AM0016<br />

were concentrated in the second half of 2005<br />

and then stopped. A second wave of pig projects<br />

started in 2006 and were developed using the<br />

small-scale methodology AMS III.D. In 2007 very<br />

few projects of this kind started validation.<br />

Most of these projects consisted of bundling many<br />

farms in just one PDD. The project proponents<br />

are generally companies with their main business<br />

in the development and management of <strong>CDM</strong><br />

project activities. They developed the project<br />

and proposed it to a number of farms, mostly<br />

organized in cooperatives or associations. For<br />

the farm owners, the benefits are reductions in<br />

local environmental impacts and having the heat<br />

and/or energy to be used on the farm. Project<br />

developers assume all the costs and risks and are<br />

the owners of the CERs. In some projects, farmers<br />

earn a small part of the CERs. These projects face<br />

some additional difficulties because farms can<br />

Nevertheless it is unquestionable that the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

is a success and has introduced structural<br />

changes in some sectors in some countries.<br />

be very far away from each other and operational<br />

costs and logistics are complicated. At present<br />

not many project developers are interested in<br />

developing this kind of project due to all these<br />

hurdles.<br />

How the prospect of developing Programmatic<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> will impact on this kind of project is not<br />

clear. Programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> allows an unlimited<br />

and continuous addition of project activities<br />

(CPA), replicating the first one after approving<br />

the umbrella project (PoA). The idea is very<br />

interesting because it allows costs to be reduced<br />

and some projects to be scaled up, thus reducing<br />

the bureaucracy. However, other problems, like<br />

the reaction of the DOEs in assuming their role,<br />

are delaying the adoption of this <strong>new</strong> modality <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>CDM</strong>. A big pig-product company is developing<br />

a Programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> in Brazil. The advantage<br />

in terms of adding farms continuously is clear,<br />

but the overall perception is that the marketing<br />

associated with the trade mark was also important<br />

in the decision to go <strong>for</strong>ward with this project.<br />

Towards Structural Change <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development in Some Sectors<br />

29<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


This will probably be the first Programmatic<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> to be analysed in the Brazilian DNA.<br />

In terms of the capacity to modify practices in<br />

the sector, it is clear that this practice is being<br />

incorporated as part of the modernization of<br />

these farms. There is an important gap between<br />

the traditional practices in low-intensity capital<br />

family farms and modern farms with high levels<br />

of technology. The technology <strong>for</strong> the use of<br />

biogas is not feasible <strong>for</strong> small farms. One great<br />

challenge is to extend this practice to smaller<br />

farms. The impact in the long term is positive. It<br />

is interesting to note that workers on the farms<br />

have a great interest in maintaining the systems<br />

that have already been embedded because they<br />

bring great advantages in terms of working<br />

conditions. The challenge is to interest farmers<br />

in the secondary benefits of using biogas, like<br />

the electricity, heat and fertilizers that could be<br />

produced, as well as the attractiveness of a better<br />

local environment, even if the business is very<br />

marginal in terms of the core business.<br />

Bagasse<br />

This kind of project activity consists in increasing<br />

the steam efficiency of a bagasse cogeneration<br />

facility and supplying the electricity surplus<br />

to the grid. This avoids dispatching the same<br />

amount of energy, which is part fossil. There<br />

are 51 bagasse cogeneration projects in the<br />

pipeline, contributing 6% of expected CERs<br />

until 2012. Most of them use large-scale<br />

methodologies. Until 2005 the methodology<br />

used was AM0015, but from 2006 onward the<br />

consolidated methodology ACM0006 was used<br />

in association with ACM0002. This stability of<br />

the methodologies available is very positive <strong>for</strong><br />

the development of projects.<br />

The current situation is that bagasse is used<br />

<strong>for</strong> cogeneration in very inefficient facilities,<br />

and no electricity is supplied to the grid. The<br />

high potential <strong>for</strong> energy production from the<br />

sugarcane industry was repeatedly pointed out<br />

in many studies on the energy sector. However,<br />

this potential was never utilized. There are many<br />

reasons <strong>for</strong> this. First of all, bagasse is abundant,<br />

and if it remains on the field it represents an<br />

environmental problem. Burning it in a very<br />

inefficient way is convenient because the costs<br />

are low. This consumes a lot of bagasse and<br />

generates sufficient electricity and heat <strong>for</strong><br />

the sugarcane industry. The ability to supply<br />

energy to the grid was made possible in the <strong>new</strong><br />

regulations <strong>for</strong> the electricity sector, but it was<br />

not sufficient <strong>for</strong> the sector to move on in this<br />

direction. There are many reasons <strong>for</strong> this. The<br />

main reason is that producing electricity is not<br />

the sector’s core business. Energy production<br />

could represent 1% or 2% of the core business,<br />

namely the production of sugar and/or ethanol.<br />

Investment in high-efficient boilers and turbogenerators<br />

is not required in order to continue<br />

or increase the production of sugar or/and<br />

ethanol. Producers are not interested in going<br />

into another business (energy). They would need<br />

to supply energy on a regular basis and to comply<br />

with many technical specifications <strong>for</strong> a sector<br />

with a different logic and behaviour than in the<br />

agro-industry. It would imply significant changes<br />

<strong>for</strong> a marginal gain with many risks. Only after<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> did the sugarcane industry start to supply<br />

electricity to the grid. This is unequivocal.<br />

The contribution to sustainable development,<br />

as stated in Annex III of the PDDs, is associated<br />

rather with the particular industry as a whole<br />

and cannot be associated directly with the<br />

project activity. Usually the industries which<br />

adhere to the <strong>CDM</strong> have better practices in<br />

terms of benefits to employees and their families,<br />

30<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


working conditions, etc. Some PDDs state that<br />

some of the CERs will revert to local projects in<br />

the social area. But in the long term, the main<br />

contribution relates to the use of a by-product<br />

as an energy source. As everyone knows, Brazil<br />

has a very low carbon intensive energy matrix<br />

and electricity generation is based mainly on<br />

hydropower sources. What is interesting is that<br />

the dry season coincides with the sugarcane<br />

harvest season, which permits a very convenient<br />

complementarity. During the dry season the<br />

level of the water in the reservoirs has to be<br />

controlled, and this is the period when thermopower<br />

plants are dispatched more frequently.<br />

This complementarity is positive because it<br />

reduces emissions from fossil fuels and enhances<br />

the stability of the Brazilian electricity system<br />

by adding firm energy to the system. As UNICA,<br />

the Brazilian Sugarcane Industry Association,<br />

states, the potential <strong>for</strong> power generation with<br />

bagasse in 2020 is 15,214 MW. Adding straw to<br />

the bagasse, the potential reaches 28,758 MW. So<br />

this kind of project still has a great potential as<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project activity.<br />

Projects which generate<br />

electricity <strong>for</strong> the grid<br />

Many types of project generate electricity <strong>for</strong> the<br />

grid (Figure 2) or replace the energy supplied by<br />

the grid. From a total of 280 project activities, 148<br />

generate electricity with an installed capacity of<br />

5958 MW and emissions reductions of 81,867 t<br />

CO2 until 2012. Some of these have been dealt<br />

with in previous sections, like hydro-power and<br />

bagasse <strong>CDM</strong> projects, but some others, like windpower<br />

plants or solar energy, were not addressed<br />

because they are not numerous. It is important to<br />

understand why these projects are not numerous<br />

and how <strong>CDM</strong> could play an important role in<br />

preventing increases in the carbon intensity of<br />

the Brazilian energy matrix.<br />

The main source of electricity generation in<br />

Brazil is hydropower plants. This makes the<br />

emissions factor <strong>for</strong> the grid very low compared<br />

to other host countries like India and China, with<br />

a mainly coal-based matrix. Nevertheless 149<br />

projects, more than 50% per cent of the projects<br />

in the pipeline, are <strong>for</strong> producing electricity.<br />

Most of these projects use ACM0002 or AMS ID,<br />

which have the same rationale <strong>for</strong> calculating<br />

the emissions factor. The rationale behind the<br />

methodology, which estimates the emissions<br />

factor <strong>for</strong> an electricity system, is not adequate<br />

<strong>for</strong> a country like Brazil, which has very low<br />

operating margins because of the huge number<br />

of hydropower plants (low cost must run)<br />

generating electricity in the base. The build<br />

margin, which takes into account the most<br />

recently constructed power plants, responsible<br />

<strong>for</strong> 20% of the electricity generation in the<br />

system, does not reflect what is happening in<br />

the energy auctions. Only thermo power plants<br />

can offer the minimum price and hence win the<br />

auction and get constructed. Re<strong>new</strong>ables go to<br />

the auction but do not win. Calculated in this<br />

Figure 2 –<strong>CDM</strong> project activities generating electricity<br />

Towards Structural Change <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development in Some Sectors<br />

31<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


way, the build margin emissions factor is very low<br />

<strong>for</strong> Brazil and does not represent an incentive <strong>for</strong><br />

re<strong>new</strong>able projects. To give an idea, I will present<br />

the results from the last two auctions realized on<br />

September 2008 to decide which plants will start<br />

to generate electricity to the interconnected<br />

system. In the first auction (1,935.39 MW), all the<br />

plants that win the bid were fossil fuel: ten fuel-oil<br />

plants and two natural-gas plants. In the second<br />

bid (5,566 MW), 24 plants were (contracted?),<br />

of which 17 were fuel-oil plants, four natural gas<br />

and one coal. Only two re<strong>new</strong>able plants were<br />

contracted: one bagasse and one hydropower<br />

plant.<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong> has had a great impact in<br />

Brazil. It has been a fabulous showroom of<br />

possible <strong>new</strong> practices in the country, like<br />

landfills with vegetation and birds, pig farms<br />

producing heat electricity, and fertilizers<br />

without bad smells using all sorts of biomass<br />

by-products to produce electricity, etc.<br />

The trend is very clear: of the installed capacity of<br />

101,520 MW, only 21% represents thermo power<br />

plants. Of the plants which are in construction<br />

(7,643 MW), 25% are thermo, and of those which<br />

have not started construction yet (26,981 MW),<br />

45% are thermal power plants.<br />

As demonstrated, Brazil has very clean electricity,<br />

but this reality is changing. The way in which<br />

ACM0002 or the “tool to calculate the emissions<br />

factor <strong>for</strong> an electricity system” is calculating<br />

the emissions factor in order to quantify the<br />

emissions reductions of <strong>CDM</strong> projects captures<br />

the inertia of the system instead of looking ahead<br />

and identifying the trend. <strong>CDM</strong> should be an<br />

incentive to reverse this scenario of increasing<br />

carbon intensity. Un<strong>for</strong>tunately this is not the<br />

case <strong>for</strong> the Brazilian electricity matrix.<br />

Another difficulty is related to the definition<br />

of the electrical system <strong>for</strong> the grid and the<br />

emissions factors associated with this definition,<br />

which have changed in the country. Initially<br />

projects used the simple adjusted method <strong>for</strong> the<br />

operating margin and used a definition <strong>for</strong> the<br />

grid by gathering the south and the southeast/<br />

central regions into only one grid. Most of the<br />

projects that added power to the grid are located<br />

in the southeast region. When the Dispatch<br />

Centre started to calculate the emissions factor<br />

by means of the dispatch analysis, another<br />

grid definition was used, which is the common<br />

definition used by the dispatch analysis in<br />

its commercial contracts. Finally, a study was<br />

per<strong>for</strong>med by the Dispatch Centre together<br />

with the Ministry of Mines and Energy and the<br />

Ministry of Science and Technology by applying<br />

the criteria proposed in the “Tool to calculate<br />

the emission factor <strong>for</strong> an electricity system” to<br />

the Brazilian electricity system. After this study,<br />

<strong>for</strong> the purpose of the <strong>CDM</strong>, the Brazilian grid<br />

was defined as only one system. What are the<br />

consequences of these definitions? As most coal<br />

power plants are in the South, the emissions<br />

factor taking the South into account becomes<br />

higher. But in fact, as the country is highly<br />

interconnected, it does not matter where the<br />

energy is produced <strong>for</strong> the logic of the dispatch.<br />

In terms of sustainable development, it is highly<br />

significant that there is only one emissions<br />

factor <strong>for</strong> the country. This will create incentives<br />

<strong>for</strong> many projects that otherwise would not be<br />

carried out, and the energy will be available <strong>for</strong><br />

the whole country because of the increasing<br />

interconnection. Now, <strong>for</strong> example, there will<br />

be greater incentives <strong>for</strong> wind-power projects<br />

32<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


in the Northeast of the country, which has great<br />

unused potential, and the previous baseline<br />

emissions factor <strong>for</strong> the region was almost zero.<br />

This <strong>new</strong> baseline emissions factor associated<br />

with Programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> may help to disseminate<br />

many technologies. For example, the use of<br />

electric showers is very common in Brazil, which<br />

produces two demand peaks during the day and<br />

increase the need <strong>for</strong> firm energy. The use of<br />

solar heaters, which is almost inexistent, could<br />

be a real benefit <strong>for</strong> the country.<br />

Finally, the projects in the pipeline that have<br />

been analysed in this paper do not yet reflect<br />

the <strong>new</strong> emissions factors, which are lower than<br />

the previous ones <strong>for</strong> some regions (South and<br />

Southeast/Center) but are higher <strong>for</strong> others<br />

(North and Northeast), which coincidentally are<br />

the less developed areas in the country.<br />

Final Remarks<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong> has had a great impact in Brazil.<br />

It has been a fabulous showroom of possible<br />

<strong>new</strong> practices in the country, like landfills with<br />

vegetation and birds, pig farms producing heat<br />

electricity, and fertilizers without bad smells<br />

using all sorts of biomass by-products to produce<br />

electricity, etc. In terms of structural changes,<br />

which allow the <strong>new</strong> practices that have been<br />

introduced to become common practice, the<br />

impacts differ greatly from sector to sector, but<br />

in general projects would not survive without the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>. More research is needed to understand and<br />

explain the overall dynamic and driving <strong>for</strong>ces in<br />

each sector/technology. The main aspect of the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> was to call the attention of the production<br />

sector to the fact that from now on climate<br />

change is an important aspect to be taken into<br />

account. The perception that this <strong>new</strong> constraint<br />

can also be trans<strong>for</strong>med into a <strong>new</strong> business<br />

opportunity allowing the country to grow in a<br />

more sustainable way was very important. This<br />

change in mentality and the perception of <strong>new</strong><br />

opportunities in some sectors are the main<br />

achievements. Two main deceptions remain. As<br />

all over the world, no small-scale projects <strong>for</strong><br />

poor communities are being developed in Brazil<br />

and almost no project activities in af<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

and re<strong>for</strong>estation. Probably <strong>CDM</strong> is not the<br />

best mechanism to develop these kinds of<br />

projects. Now in Brazil the public sector, like<br />

municipalities, ministries and agencies, is very<br />

interested in developing Programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> in<br />

many of these areas which have not yet been<br />

covered by the <strong>CDM</strong> projects, like re<strong>for</strong>estation,<br />

public transportation, energy efficiency, etc.<br />

There is an enormous need <strong>for</strong> development<br />

in the country. Climate change must not be a<br />

limitation <strong>for</strong> development and eradication of<br />

poverty. Rather, it will be an opportunity <strong>for</strong> a<br />

sustainable development, which is viable in the<br />

long term, efficient, fair and with low carbon<br />

intensity. The process is just beginning.<br />

Branca AMERICANO has worked since 1998 at the Coordination<br />

on Global Climate Change of the Brazilian Ministry of Science and<br />

Technology, which is also the Executive Secretariat of the Brazilian<br />

DNA. She has participated in the IPCC-EFDB Steering Group<br />

and is a negotiator in the Brazilian delegation to the UNFCCC.<br />

Contact: branca.americano@gmail.com<br />

Towards Structural Change <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development in Some Sectors<br />

33<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


34<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


David Lesolle<br />

DNA in Botswana<br />

Perspectives from Africa on<br />

a <strong>Re<strong>for</strong>med</strong> <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Abstract<br />

The Clean Development Mechanism (<strong>CDM</strong>) has<br />

proved to be a success in generating projects<br />

to address the greenhouse gas emissions that<br />

would otherwise have occurred in developing<br />

countries. Despite Africa’s growing participation<br />

in the carbon market, African projects accounted<br />

<strong>for</strong> about 4% of <strong>CDM</strong> projects by mid-2008<br />

(UNFCCC website, August 2008). Based on<br />

the above assessment, there is a need <strong>for</strong> a<br />

special approach to <strong>CDM</strong> to ensure that Africa’s<br />

participation is enhanced. The regional differences<br />

and geographical distribution identify capacity and<br />

experience as key drivers <strong>for</strong> the low per<strong>for</strong>mance<br />

by the rest of Africa. The countries that have<br />

attained some level of sustainable development<br />

are those that are likely to benefit from <strong>CDM</strong>,<br />

namely South Africa and North Africa. The<br />

paper examines what needs to happen to re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> to benefit Africa: institutional re<strong>for</strong>ms,<br />

management systems and capacity-building.<br />

Africa and the Clean<br />

Development Mechanism<br />

Since the Kyoto Protocol became fully operational<br />

in 2005, the Clean Development Mechanism<br />

has become a multi-billion dollar source of<br />

funding <strong>for</strong> sustainable development. In his<br />

address to the 13 th Conference of the Parties to<br />

the United Nations Framework Convention on<br />

Climate Change (UNFCCC) in Nairobi in 2007,<br />

the Secretary General of the UN, Ban Kii Moon,<br />

identified the mechanism as an ‘outstanding<br />

example of a UN-led partnership linking<br />

government action to the private sector in the<br />

developing world’.<br />

35<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Table 1: Countries with <strong>CDM</strong> projects in Africa - by number<br />

and scale (expressed as thousands of certified emission reduction<br />

(kCER) expected in 2012).<br />

on sustainable development, especially if <strong>CDM</strong><br />

project activities are to become popular in<br />

Africa. The problem with <strong>CDM</strong> so far is that it<br />

has <strong>for</strong>gotten about sustainable development<br />

and tends to award prominence to mitigation<br />

and emissions reduction.<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project activities are sparsely distributed<br />

across Africa (Table 2). In most cases, the lack of<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> activity is closely tied to the level of awareness<br />

of the role-players – the DNA, the private<br />

sector and the civil-society movement on climate<br />

change issues in general.<br />

Challenges leading to low levels<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong> Activity in Africa<br />

Source: UNEP Risø <strong>CDM</strong> Pipeline 1 September 2008. www.pipeline.org<br />

Since then, the numbers show a rather slower<br />

pace of movement <strong>for</strong> Africa (see Table 1). The<br />

experience of African countries has been a steep<br />

learning curve. The opportunities are there, and,<br />

as we go into the fourth review of the Global<br />

Environmental Facility (GEF), there will be a need<br />

to ensure that Africa’s specific circumstances are<br />

addressed. For this to happen, African negotiators<br />

must prepare themselves to engage with partners,<br />

developed countries and in some cases countries<br />

belonging to the G77 and China group.<br />

Unequal geographical distribution<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong> Projects <strong>for</strong> Africa<br />

Though the number of African countries with<br />

DNAs is high compared to other regions such as<br />

the Asia/Pacific, the number of projects is not<br />

encouraging. Most African DNAs see <strong>CDM</strong> as an<br />

opportunity to drive sustainable development.<br />

It is in this regard that the focus needs to be<br />

The review of a number of initial national<br />

communications submitted to the secretariat<br />

established that (see UNFCCC website):<br />

• For many parties, the issue of climate change<br />

was <strong>new</strong> to them, as was their ef<strong>for</strong>ts in<br />

education, training and public awareness.<br />

• Unavailability of experts and limited financial<br />

resources has caused difficulties in organizing<br />

materials <strong>for</strong> education, training and public<br />

awareness.<br />

• The integration of climate change issues<br />

into educational curricula was recognized as<br />

crucial <strong>for</strong> the future.<br />

• Minimal awareness and education on climate<br />

change issues among the public at large,<br />

NGOs and policy-makers.<br />

• Many parties indicated that, in order to address<br />

climate change issues in a multidisciplinary<br />

and efficient way, they would require<br />

additional financial and technical resources<br />

to develop and train a critical mass of human<br />

resources in inventories, vulnerability and<br />

adaptation.<br />

• The scope of training on climate change<br />

issues should be widened, to include data<br />

36<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Table 2<br />

Region KP parties Parties with DNA Parties with project experience Parties with registered projects<br />

Annex 1 parties (AI) 38 28 n/a* 17<br />

NAI-Africa (NAI-AFR) 47 37 16 7<br />

NAI-Asia and the Pacific (NAI-ASP) 49 34 28 21<br />

NAI-Latin America and the Caribbean<br />

(NAI-LAC)<br />

32 26 19 19<br />

NAI-Other 7 8 6 3<br />

UNFCCC website. August 2008.<br />

and uncertainty analysis and vulnerability<br />

and adaptation assessments at both the basic<br />

and advanced levels.<br />

Though the findings from the review of initial<br />

national communications were <strong>for</strong> all developing<br />

countries, they are also very specific to African<br />

countries.<br />

The other reason leading to low levels of activity in<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> as a strategy <strong>for</strong> reducing global emissions<br />

of GHGs in Africa has also been the chaotic<br />

nature of responses. Most African DNAs had<br />

imagined that “<strong>CDM</strong> world” would take <strong>for</strong>m of a<br />

governmental process – very <strong>for</strong>mal and easy to<br />

follow. 1 What actually emerged was a <strong>CDM</strong> that<br />

was very difficult to follow, with a lot of players all<br />

vying <strong>for</strong> the different products delivered by <strong>CDM</strong><br />

– CERs, VERs (Voluntary Emission Reductions)<br />

and, to add to the pain, a number of funding<br />

windows.<br />

The different implementation strategies <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong><br />

in the eyes of Africans has also led to the creation<br />

of several types of in<strong>for</strong>mal financial services –<br />

financiers, brokers and <strong>new</strong> financial packages<br />

1 Personal communication from the very small emitting countries, such<br />

as Lesotho, Namibia and others.<br />

– parallel to <strong>CDM</strong>, <strong>including</strong>, <strong>for</strong> example, ‘the<br />

Cool Earth Partnership’ and different standards<br />

being applied to CERs.<br />

African enterprises – particularly those that are<br />

taking part in the global market and exporting<br />

various commodities, ranging from agricultural<br />

derivatives via beef, fruit and sweet corn, to textiles<br />

to mining – have already undertaken emissionsreducing<br />

activities on their own initiative, mostly<br />

to ensure that they remained competitive and<br />

did not lose their markets. Un<strong>for</strong>tunately these<br />

projects were not registered with the DNAs, so,<br />

with no baseline developed, African countries<br />

kept losing out on the opportunities that <strong>CDM</strong><br />

was to bring. In the meantime, Africa continues to<br />

see the development of various projects, ranging<br />

from energy crops to transport to af<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

and re<strong>for</strong>estation.<br />

Africa has a number of potential <strong>CDM</strong> projects,<br />

particularly in areas such as waste, energy<br />

efficiency and re<strong>new</strong>able energy options. The<br />

opportunities are attractive; methodologies are<br />

available, and there are also the experiences of<br />

other regions to learn from, especially South<br />

America, which African countries may draw on in<br />

developing <strong>CDM</strong> further to address their specific<br />

development needs.<br />

Improving Price Equity in <strong>CDM</strong> Projects: Strategies <strong>for</strong> Maximizing Carbon Value<br />

37<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


<strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong> Sustainable<br />

Development: re<strong>for</strong>ms<br />

necessary <strong>for</strong> Africa<br />

A number of re<strong>for</strong>ms are necessary <strong>for</strong> African<br />

countries to participate meaningfully in <strong>CDM</strong> and<br />

to ensure that <strong>CDM</strong> delivers what it was meant to.<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> and Sustainable<br />

Development: the vital link<br />

The UNFCCC objective (Article 2) broadly identifies<br />

two options <strong>for</strong> intervention: adaptation<br />

and mitigation. The focus in applying <strong>CDM</strong> has<br />

only been on mitigation. The only link between<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> and adaptation is the share of the proceeds<br />

of 2% of the sale of CERs as a contribution to the<br />

Adaptation Fund.<br />

Several African DNAs define sustainable development<br />

as essentially driven by socio-economic and<br />

environmental factors. The expectation is that<br />

adaptation and mitigation will be considered<br />

in tandem and that there<strong>for</strong>e any financial<br />

mechanism must be applied to both management<br />

options.<br />

Most governments still perceive issues of global<br />

warming and climate change as environmental<br />

concerns and there<strong>for</strong>e place greater emphasis<br />

on environmental response strategies. This means<br />

that a number of projects with the potential <strong>for</strong><br />

benefitting from <strong>CDM</strong> do not do so. For example,<br />

waste – a potential sector <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> – is not easily<br />

perceived as a potential energy resource. It will<br />

take a few examples to generate the catalytic effect<br />

to promote <strong>CDM</strong> as an associate measure and to<br />

use it to achieve sustainable development.<br />

What needs to happen to achieve<br />

sustainable development?<br />

Africa has no option but to elect sustainable<br />

development as the only vehicle of choice in<br />

meeting the challenges emanating from the<br />

vagaries caused by global warming and climate<br />

change. This choice is largely driven by the<br />

following key factors:<br />

Carbon emissions and Africa<br />

Africa contributes less than 4% 2 to global GHG<br />

emissions. Historically this figure has been even lower<br />

– Africa’s contribution to the GHG concentrations in<br />

the atmosphere is miniscule. This also presents itself<br />

as an opportunity <strong>for</strong> clean development, but only if<br />

sustainable development were to be emphasized in<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong>. Many people in African countries rely on<br />

wood <strong>for</strong> fuel, which is used <strong>for</strong> cooking, lighting and<br />

in colder winters also <strong>for</strong> heating. There are a number<br />

of projects aimed at reducing the amount of emissions<br />

that occur as a result. One aspect remains, however:<br />

the cultural attachment to cooking with firewood.<br />

Future re<strong>for</strong>ms to <strong>CDM</strong> need to recognize these<br />

cultural aspects and to relate the GHG emissions to<br />

health and the other benefits that would result.<br />

Additionality and SD <strong>for</strong> Africa<br />

Low levels of development mean that Africa is<br />

bound to benefit from implementing <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activities. At the same time, a number of projects<br />

are still challenged by the application of the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> eligibility criteria, such as the procedures<br />

required to demonstrate the eligibility of lands<br />

<strong>for</strong> af<strong>for</strong>estation and re<strong>for</strong>estation. Since most<br />

of the African population relies on subsistence<br />

agriculture, large amounts of land are cleared<br />

<strong>for</strong> this purpose. At the same time, firewood<br />

is as a primary energy source, which means<br />

2 World Bank Statistics, 1996. IPCC AR4.<br />

38<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


that national baselines are low. How, then, will<br />

Africa achieve food security and implement<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> when GHG emissions from agricultural<br />

practices are significant? At the same time, Africa<br />

must develop to meet the demands of rising<br />

populations <strong>for</strong> better health, food security,<br />

improved infrastructure <strong>for</strong> roads, water and<br />

communications.<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> and Adaptation<br />

Global warming and climate change pose very<br />

serious challenges <strong>for</strong> Africa. Droughts, food<br />

security and extreme weather events related to<br />

climate change are already having a bearing on<br />

African economies. Climate change adaptation<br />

remains a viable option. <strong>CDM</strong> must in the<br />

future consider these realities.<br />

Necessary <strong>CDM</strong> structural and institutional<br />

re<strong>for</strong>ms to stimulate Africa’s participation in<br />

<strong>CDM</strong><br />

There are a number of <strong>CDM</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms that need to<br />

take place to stimulate Africa’s participation in<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>. The <strong>CDM</strong> process itself needs review and<br />

simplification. Currently it involves a series of<br />

complicated steps. This in itself poses difficulties<br />

and hinders Africa’s participation in the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

process.<br />

Sustainable development and <strong>CDM</strong><br />

In a number of African countries, DNAs have<br />

developed or are in the process of refining their<br />

sustainable development criteria. The African<br />

sustainable development criterion typically has<br />

the following requirements: income-generation,<br />

environmental sustainability, employment-generation,<br />

capacity-building and technological develop<br />

ment.<br />

While it is important that sustainable development<br />

should be the goal, the output is already defined.<br />

Africa must at the same time reduce greenhouse<br />

gas emissions, otherwise the project activities will<br />

not qualify as <strong>CDM</strong> project activities. Sustainable<br />

development must there<strong>for</strong>e be a measure, not<br />

an objective, and the indicators are likely to show<br />

changes in employment levels, livelihoods and so<br />

on.<br />

Africa has a number of potential <strong>CDM</strong><br />

projects, particularly in areas such as waste,<br />

energy efficiency and re<strong>new</strong>able energy options.<br />

By making sustainable development an indicator<br />

<strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong>, one assumes that the components of<br />

the indicator will be measured. Who is going to<br />

do this? Should African DNAs now be verifying<br />

sustainable development <strong>for</strong> each project? And<br />

the question is, is this where we, Africa, should<br />

be devoting our energy?<br />

Communication strategy <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong><br />

<strong>CDM</strong> needs to be communicated appropriately.<br />

Africa remains very vulnerable to misin<strong>for</strong>mation<br />

by vendors and brokers until an appropriate<br />

communications plan has been put into effect<br />

<strong>for</strong> the continent.<br />

The communication strategy must be driven by a<br />

capacitated DNA and local committees in place<br />

in African countries. These may inter alia include<br />

the national committees <strong>for</strong> the development of<br />

national communications.<br />

The communication strategy must consider<br />

the void in environmental journalism. Most of<br />

the readership is still struggling with issues<br />

of governance, civil issues, food security and<br />

Improving Price Equity in <strong>CDM</strong> Projects: Strategies <strong>for</strong> Maximizing Carbon Value<br />

39<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


development, to the extent that environment is<br />

relegated to almost the last priority level. The<br />

media must also be part of any communications<br />

strategy.<br />

Institutional framework and<br />

per<strong>for</strong>mance systems<br />

The current situation is there<strong>for</strong>e not the best<br />

suited <strong>for</strong> Africa. Most DNAs are there<strong>for</strong>e not<br />

active. There are a number of factors that demand<br />

institutional re<strong>for</strong>m:<br />

• The difficulty is in understanding key<br />

issues such as validation: whether or not<br />

to allow cheap projects? This is especially<br />

the case, given that the private sector is<br />

generally starved of additional resources<br />

to invest in project development and<br />

validation.<br />

• The capacity of DNAs to participate<br />

effectively in the <strong>CDM</strong> and institutional<br />

appropriateness. Most DNAs are strongly<br />

associated with the foci of the UNFCCC,<br />

which itself happened to be anchored<br />

within the departments of meteorology,<br />

hydrology or the environment portfolio<br />

in general. The key questions are: Is<br />

this the most effective configuration?<br />

Does it matter where the anchor is?<br />

What additional capacity-building and<br />

institutional strengthening initiatives<br />

would be necessary?<br />

• The per<strong>for</strong>mance of the DNAs and <strong>CDM</strong><br />

activity are not emphasized, and nor is<br />

geographical inequity in the distribution<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong> project activities. The <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Executive Board may be requested<br />

by the Conference of the Parties to<br />

the UNFCCC to take this challenge<br />

as a measure of the per<strong>for</strong>mance and<br />

effectiveness of the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

The Nairobi Framework:<br />

placing a particular<br />

emphasis on Africa<br />

The Nairobi Framework, one of the significant<br />

outcomes of the Nairobi Climate Change Conference<br />

in 2006, is a plan to support developing<br />

countries and participate in the Clean Development<br />

Mechanism, especially in Africa. The Nairobi<br />

Framework has five objectives to move the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

<strong>for</strong>ward in the beneficiary countries:<br />

• Build and enhance the capacity of DNAs<br />

to become fully operational<br />

• Build capacity in developing <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activities<br />

• Promote investment opportunities <strong>for</strong><br />

pro jects<br />

• Improve in<strong>for</strong>mation sharing/<br />

outreach/exchange of views on<br />

activities/education and training<br />

• Inter-agency coordination<br />

The Nairobi Framework recognized the lack of<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> activity in Africa. Out of the total of 47<br />

African Parties to the Kyoto Protocol, 37 have<br />

Designated National Authorities (DNAs), and of<br />

these only 16 have projects. On 14 April 2008,<br />

the global community celebrated the 1000 th<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project. The African DNAs are sitting idle<br />

– probably not yet ready to go.<br />

Though <strong>CDM</strong> has been in place <strong>for</strong> some time,<br />

it is evident that there is still more work to be<br />

undertaken to implement the spirit of the Nairobi<br />

Framework.<br />

40<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Making the Nairobi Framework<br />

deliver: re<strong>for</strong>ms necessary to enhance<br />

Africa’s participation in <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Historically, <strong>CDM</strong> has placed the emphasis on<br />

carbon emissions reduction, energy efficiency<br />

and conservation, and less on sustainable<br />

development. To drive the SD agenda further<br />

<strong>for</strong>ward, <strong>new</strong> methodologies must be developed,<br />

especially in those sectors where Africa has<br />

potential. This would minimize the cost<br />

associated with project development and also<br />

allow small-scale African projects to benefit<br />

from <strong>CDM</strong>. There are opportunities in transport,<br />

power transmission and distribution, and in<br />

sectors which use wood fuel.<br />

Build and enhance the capacity of<br />

DNAs to become fully operational;<br />

capacity and critical mass concept<br />

Currently very few people are active in<br />

discussions on climate change, <strong>CDM</strong> or carbon<br />

finance concepts. The few, usually counted in<br />

tens per country, are themselves not very well<br />

versed in these matters. The few would have<br />

benefitted from their participation as IPCC<br />

authors or participants in the UNFCCC process,<br />

and indeed may include individuals who may<br />

have also participated in the carbon <strong>for</strong>ums and<br />

expositions.<br />

In developing re<strong>for</strong>ms <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong> Africa, one<br />

necessary condition is that a critical mass must<br />

prevail. To develop and maintain a critical mass,<br />

the future <strong>CDM</strong> and DNA capacity-building<br />

programme could follow a three-step approach:<br />

• Allow <strong>for</strong> the institutional strengthening<br />

and resourcing of DNA. This will enable<br />

DNAs to have specific and targeted<br />

resources <strong>for</strong> communication, project<br />

development, training of DNA personnel<br />

and funding the participation of additional<br />

personnel in DNA regional and<br />

international activities and programmes.<br />

• Develop and finance a scholarship programme<br />

in local universities <strong>for</strong> stu dents<br />

to undertake graduate climate-change<br />

studies across the main sectors. The<br />

sectors would be country-specific and<br />

should include finance and commerce,<br />

law, agriculture, water, social-sciences<br />

faculties, etc. The cost of training an African<br />

student in Africa would almost equal the<br />

cost of an airline ticket to Europe. The<br />

critical mass <strong>for</strong> this programme must be<br />

set at a minimum of twenty such graduate<br />

students. The net benefit and gain to the<br />

DNA and African countries is that the<br />

faculty is developed and the participation<br />

of Africans in the <strong>CDM</strong> process would be<br />

strengthened without necessarily being<br />

policy prescriptive.<br />

• Allow <strong>for</strong> and facilitate skills <strong>for</strong> developing<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project proposals through south-south<br />

cooperation and north-south exchanges.<br />

This should not only aim at academia and<br />

the private sector but also the NGO and civil<br />

society.<br />

Promote investment opportunities <strong>for</strong> projects<br />

that enhance the role of the private sector<br />

The annual emissions reductions from the current<br />

projects being implemented across Africa show<br />

that most of them are of small and medium scale.<br />

This apparently is also the scale of private-sector<br />

activities in Africa, except <strong>for</strong> a few countries like<br />

South Africa, <strong>for</strong> example.<br />

In light of this reality, the role the private sector<br />

plays needs to be different and to take a different<br />

Improving Price Equity in <strong>CDM</strong> Projects: Strategies <strong>for</strong> Maximizing Carbon Value<br />

41<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


approach. <strong>CDM</strong> is not well understood 3 by the<br />

private sector, e.g. how they may benefit not only<br />

from technology transfer, but also from carbon<br />

financing and emissions trading. In most cases,<br />

the immediate response of the private sector is<br />

to change to energy-efficient modes on their<br />

own initiative, without using the <strong>CDM</strong> window.<br />

In this way they strangle their limited financial<br />

resources and profits in fear of recriminations<br />

from government. There is also a need <strong>for</strong><br />

Africa’s private sector to acquire an improved<br />

understanding of the legal aspects related to<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project activities. In some cases, the private<br />

sector has signed off the CER opportunity without<br />

realizing the financial incentives, thus entering<br />

into emissions-reduction purchase agreements<br />

without full knowledge.<br />

Unlike the private sector in other regions of<br />

developing countries, in the African region the<br />

sector is limited to infrastructure and investment.<br />

In most African countries, save <strong>for</strong> a few <strong>including</strong><br />

South Africa and some countries in North Africa,<br />

private-sector investment and project activities<br />

are short term, and the profits are minimal. Issues<br />

such as security, governance and corruption are<br />

usually singled out as reasons <strong>for</strong> this scenario.<br />

This there<strong>for</strong>e means that <strong>for</strong> African countries<br />

there are few opportunities to co-finance largescale<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project activities. This in itself also<br />

contributes to low levels of <strong>CDM</strong> throughput.<br />

The challenges that face the private sector in<br />

Africa may also be viewed as opportunities <strong>for</strong><br />

specific interventions. There is a need to enable<br />

the private sector so that it may link <strong>CDM</strong> to<br />

sustainable development and sustainable energy<br />

development objectives.<br />

3 UNEP Collaborating Centre <strong>for</strong> Energy and Environment (UCCEE),<br />

Accra, Ghana, 1998, in cooperation with Ghana EPA, IEA, UNDP and<br />

UNCTAD and sponsored by DANIDA and UNEP.<br />

The possible and immediate solution may be<br />

to ensure that specific funding is available to<br />

assist the private sector in African countries to<br />

recognize <strong>CDM</strong> as an incentive to achieve green<br />

development and remain globally competitive.<br />

Currently, even where the sectors are sizable, this<br />

is not the case. The private sector sees <strong>CDM</strong> as<br />

a complicated and lengthy process and also as<br />

expensive because of the validation process.<br />

The financial sector has not been very active<br />

except <strong>for</strong> South Africa, where the Southern<br />

African Development Bank is active in the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> market. The financial sector needs to be<br />

stimulated to see carbon finance as another<br />

way of improving the bankability of projects<br />

they are already financing, thus minimizing<br />

risks or improving security. In South American<br />

countries, the financial sector is actively involved<br />

in developing <strong>CDM</strong> methodologies to promote<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project activities or otherwise in the<br />

trading of carbon finance accruing from <strong>CDM</strong><br />

project activities. New methodologies could<br />

be developed <strong>for</strong> Africa’s main sectors, such as<br />

public transport and firewood being replaced<br />

with solar energy, while also focusing on smallscale<br />

projects.<br />

In setting goals <strong>for</strong> African <strong>CDM</strong> initiatives, the<br />

following issues must be considered:<br />

• Opportunities <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development<br />

need to drive <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

• Removing the monkey load from <strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong> SD:<br />

Africa must ensure that sustainable development<br />

does not become a load. Currently<br />

a number of countries are insisting<br />

on SD as if to mean that the sustainable<br />

development will be monitored. This is<br />

a very heavy load <strong>for</strong> DNAs, as it is timeconsuming<br />

to implement. Africa must<br />

ensure that future <strong>CDM</strong> will not commit<br />

and overstretch limited resources to evaluation.<br />

42<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


• Guarantee clean development. Though the<br />

GHG emissions <strong>for</strong> development are small,<br />

there is a need to assure that Africa’s future<br />

GHG emissions scenarios result in<br />

and achieve minimum GHG emissions.<br />

• Implement <strong>CDM</strong> while also emphasizing<br />

methods to deliver environmental and<br />

socio-economic benefits, <strong>including</strong> improved<br />

health, increased employment<br />

opportunities, etc. However, further resources<br />

should not be spent on monitoring<br />

the benefits accruing from SD.<br />

The future of <strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

Africa, post-2012<br />

Given that extending the Marrakech Accords<br />

might not be a preferred option <strong>for</strong> a number<br />

of countries – especially given that this might<br />

lead to fresh negotiations – Africa may want to<br />

consider using the opportunity <strong>for</strong> the future<br />

review of the <strong>CDM</strong>. The Bali Action Plan was<br />

launched <strong>for</strong> this purpose in December 2007<br />

(decision1/CP.13) and is meant to enable full,<br />

effective and sustained implementation. The<br />

key elements of the Bali Action Plan include:<br />

(a) A shared vision <strong>for</strong> long-term cooperative<br />

action<br />

(b) Enhanced national/international action<br />

on mitigation of climate change<br />

(c) Enhanced action on adaptation<br />

(d) Enhanced action on technology development<br />

and transfer to support action on<br />

mitigation and adaptation<br />

(e) Enhanced action on the provision of financial<br />

resources and investment to support<br />

action on mitigation and adaptation<br />

and technology cooperation<br />

The Bali Action Plan is likely to have an impact<br />

on the future of <strong>CDM</strong> in Africa. A shared vision<br />

will provide positive opportunities if, and only<br />

if, it will also open up south-south cooperation<br />

potentials without compromising the value of<br />

the CERs.<br />

Technology transfers and <strong>CDM</strong><br />

The shared vision must advance adaptation<br />

through finance and technology, <strong>including</strong><br />

national adaptation programmes of action.<br />

The shared vision must emphasize sustainable<br />

development and promote access to af<strong>for</strong>dable<br />

and environmentally sound technologies, as well<br />

as ways to accelerate the deployment, diffusion<br />

and transfer of af<strong>for</strong>dable and environmentally<br />

sound technologies.<br />

Currently very few people are active in<br />

discussions on climate change, <strong>CDM</strong> or<br />

carbon finance concepts. The few, usually<br />

counted in tens per country, are themselves<br />

not very well versed in these matters.<br />

Africa may improve its adaptive capacity through<br />

the deployment of appropriate technologies. The<br />

fourth assessment report of the IPCC indicates<br />

that the water sector is one of the key sectors<br />

that will suffer the impacts of climate change.<br />

Water needs to be sparingly used. There are<br />

opportunities to apply technologies to improved<br />

water use efficiency. <strong>CDM</strong> has yet to make use<br />

of the technology opportunities under climate<br />

change adaptation. The project activities do not<br />

directly emit greenhouse gases, but if correctly<br />

applied, these technologies can lead to emissions<br />

reduction and improved energy efficiencies. A<br />

number of programmes could be put through<br />

Improving Price Equity in <strong>CDM</strong> Projects: Strategies <strong>for</strong> Maximizing Carbon Value<br />

43<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


an experimental phase to demonstrate this<br />

opportunity, especially in the base sectors such<br />

as water and agriculture, as Africa is vulnerable<br />

to water shortages <strong>for</strong> human consumption and<br />

agricultural production. Adaptation technology<br />

applied to these sectors will also assist Africa in<br />

improving its water efficiency and food security.<br />

Making <strong>CDM</strong> work <strong>for</strong> Africa<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong> rules as they are today are complex<br />

and very cumbersome to apply and there<strong>for</strong>e<br />

open up different approaches to achieving the<br />

same outcomes. What is important is to ensure<br />

agreement on what will determine our measures<br />

<strong>for</strong> effective implementation and a shared<br />

vision.<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> needs to be extended to allow <strong>new</strong> areas,<br />

particularly where this would bring Africa<br />

on board. For example, under the <strong>CDM</strong> only<br />

af<strong>for</strong>estation and re<strong>for</strong>estation activities are<br />

eligible. For future commitment periods, <strong>CDM</strong><br />

should be considered in connection with the<br />

The private sector sees <strong>CDM</strong> as a complicated<br />

and lengthy process and also as expensive<br />

because of the validation process.<br />

process established under the CP.13 decision<br />

on “Reducing emissions from de<strong>for</strong>estation in<br />

developing countries, later known as REDD”.<br />

African countries can play a significant role in<br />

reducing emissions globally if <strong>CDM</strong> is extended<br />

to recognize REDD as a <strong>CDM</strong> project activity.<br />

De<strong>for</strong>estation is expensive to monitor, and<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> would provide the financial incentives <strong>for</strong><br />

protection and monitoring to succeed.<br />

Another strategy <strong>for</strong> making <strong>CDM</strong> work <strong>for</strong> Africa<br />

could be to allocate a share of <strong>CDM</strong> projects to<br />

Africa, <strong>for</strong> example, by setting a specific target <strong>for</strong><br />

Africa’s allocation of <strong>CDM</strong> projects. The UNFCCC<br />

Conference of the Parties may decide to set 10% or<br />

some other suitable allocation and to call <strong>for</strong> this<br />

allocation to be mainstreamed into the national<br />

programmes of Annex I parties and be reported<br />

under the national communications of Annex I<br />

parties. This would strengthen Africa’s ability to<br />

achieve sustainable development and at the same<br />

time make the continent more resilient to global<br />

warming and climate change. The allocation of<br />

a <strong>CDM</strong> share to Africa must also protect Africa<br />

from being bought cheaply. A minimum price of<br />

African CERs could be instituted with provision<br />

<strong>for</strong> revision in the future.<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> to benefit the most vulnerable<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> must there<strong>for</strong>e place an emphasis on the<br />

following key elements: how to improve <strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

the benefit of civil society, and how to bring on<br />

board the most vulnerable, who in most cases are<br />

also in countries with very little <strong>CDM</strong> potential.<br />

In the future, <strong>CDM</strong> should look beyond projectbased<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> and enhance the possibilities <strong>for</strong><br />

programmatic approaches and project-bundling<br />

strategies.<br />

Currently the climate change project activities<br />

that would also generate CERs do not fall within<br />

the guidelines <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong>. There are a number<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong>-like funds. The level of activity and<br />

participation in other regions of the world<br />

– South America, <strong>for</strong> example – in voluntary<br />

standards and other such initiatives signal<br />

the opportunities involved and the quest by<br />

the most vulnerable in participating in <strong>CDM</strong>type<br />

activities. Maybe, there<strong>for</strong>e, <strong>CDM</strong> should<br />

refine its guidelines to incorporate the <strong>new</strong> and<br />

innovative carbon finance activities.<br />

44<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


The momentum and energy <strong>for</strong> such activities<br />

need to be harnessed, and <strong>CDM</strong> can play a role<br />

in this by:<br />

• Expanding the scope of activities allowed<br />

under the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

• Defining a <strong>new</strong> role <strong>for</strong> ensuring SD<br />

through <strong>CDM</strong> by bringing on board social<br />

aspects and benefits.<br />

• Engaging the rural development community<br />

when structuring internal trading<br />

schemes, and providing legal safeguards<br />

<strong>for</strong> communities and the environment.<br />

In the future, <strong>CDM</strong> must there<strong>for</strong>e establish a<br />

common approach <strong>for</strong> such <strong>CDM</strong>-type activities,<br />

and at the same develop capacities in countries<br />

<strong>for</strong> these activities to happen.<br />

David Lesolle has extensive experience working within<br />

Botswana Government, heading a number of units and<br />

divisions, <strong>including</strong> the Climate Applications Branch.<br />

He has recently developed a climate change policy <strong>for</strong><br />

Botswana Government that emphasizes a mix of approaches.<br />

Contact: DLesolle@gov.bw<br />

Improving Price Equity in <strong>CDM</strong> Projects: Strategies <strong>for</strong> Maximizing Carbon Value<br />

45<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


46<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Diana Liverman,<br />

Emily Boyd<br />

Ox<strong>for</strong>d University<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong>, ethics and development<br />

Abstract<br />

In this paper, we address the social and ethical<br />

controversies of governing the <strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong> the<br />

poor. In order to explain why the debates are<br />

deeply polarised, we examine the key social<br />

perspectives on the mechanism and place them<br />

within fundamental debates within the social,<br />

economic and environmental sciences. We<br />

then explore the way in which <strong>CDM</strong> critiques<br />

are closely aligned with existing development<br />

thinking, identifying core narratives relating to<br />

knowledge politics, stakeholder accountability<br />

and rights-based perspectives and associated<br />

archetypical stories. In the discussion, we examine<br />

ways in which the re<strong>for</strong>m of the <strong>CDM</strong> may address<br />

some of the core barriers to its acceptance.<br />

In the run up to Copenhagen in 2009, the<br />

pressure is mounting <strong>for</strong> policy-makers to<br />

address key governance re<strong>for</strong>m challenges posed<br />

by the Clean Development Mechanism. The <strong>CDM</strong><br />

has come under criticism from many different<br />

sources – governments, local residents, and<br />

NGOs, as well as the research community. This<br />

paper focuses on perspectives from the research<br />

community, seeking to explain criticisms of the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> in terms of longstanding and deeply rooted<br />

debates about environment and development,<br />

and examines potential re<strong>for</strong>ms in terms of their<br />

ability to respond to some of these criticisms.<br />

We provide extensive references to the academic<br />

literature <strong>for</strong> those interested in understanding<br />

the origins of worldviews that are influencing the<br />

debate over the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

47<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


To date, the <strong>CDM</strong> has spurred the development<br />

of more than 4000 projects in 70 developing<br />

countries. 1 These projects are expected to reduce<br />

global greenhouse gas emissions by up to 2.6<br />

Gt CO 2<br />

-equivalent by 2012. <strong>CDM</strong> projects are<br />

at various stages of registration, validation and<br />

review in the <strong>CDM</strong> ‘pipeline’. As of September<br />

2008, more than a thousand <strong>CDM</strong> projects<br />

were registered and more than 150 were in the<br />

registration process. The majority of projects to<br />

date are large-scale methane land-fill gas projects,<br />

N 2<br />

O and re<strong>new</strong>able energy projects. The <strong>CDM</strong> is<br />

expected to generate billions of US dollars and<br />

thus also contribute to various development<br />

funds, <strong>including</strong> the adaptation fund. 2<br />

Discussion of the <strong>CDM</strong> often focuses on<br />

three issues: (i) the need to demonstrate that<br />

projects are truly additional (that the benefits<br />

to the climate and carbon cycle are more than<br />

what would have been the case otherwise); (ii)<br />

the requirement that projects contribute to<br />

sustainable development; and (iii) the extent to<br />

which industrial countries should meet their<br />

emissions commitments through the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

rather than through domestic actions. 3 Although<br />

additionality and sustainable development<br />

criteria are defined within the <strong>for</strong>mal <strong>CDM</strong><br />

procedures, there are considerable ambiguities,<br />

especially in the evaluation of sustainable<br />

development benefits. Sustainable development<br />

in the <strong>CDM</strong> relates to the measurement and<br />

monitoring of a project’s social, economic and<br />

ecological contributions and is currently assessed<br />

by the host country, but it is poorly defined.<br />

Additionality is also contested because of the<br />

need to establish a counterfactual story about<br />

what would have happened in the absence of the<br />

project and/or carbon finance. Debates about the<br />

role of the <strong>CDM</strong> in meeting emissions reduction<br />

targets resulted in the EU and several countries<br />

limiting the use of offsets because of concerns<br />

about ethics and technology innovation. 4<br />

Underlying discussions about the state and<br />

re<strong>for</strong>m of the <strong>CDM</strong> are a set of more profound<br />

disagreements about the rationale and impacts of<br />

carbon trading that are linked to the theoretical,<br />

disciplinary and political perspectives of<br />

different groups of scholars and other critics.<br />

These include arguments from economics, earth<br />

science, ethics, political science and development,<br />

which often reflect very different world views. As<br />

we will show, addressing these multiple visions in<br />

the re<strong>for</strong>m of the <strong>CDM</strong> is challenging, perhaps<br />

only being able to reflect those perspectives that<br />

are well grounded in previous experiences of<br />

development.<br />

Economic perspectives on the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

The economic argument <strong>for</strong> offsets and the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

is that greenhouse gases are externalities that<br />

can be addressed through regulation, taxation,<br />

and/or trading, and that emission reductions<br />

are cheaper and faster in the developing world. 5<br />

Thus, if scarce resources are to be devoted to<br />

emissions reductions, the rational choice is to<br />

allow countries, firms, and individuals to pay <strong>for</strong><br />

them in the developing world, where the same<br />

amount of money can buy more reductions and<br />

allow <strong>for</strong> maximum benefit at minimum cost.<br />

So, <strong>for</strong> example, an industrial country where<br />

energy efficiency is already high (such as Japan)<br />

or a sector where emissions reductions are<br />

technically difficult (such as livestock) can use<br />

offsets as a cheaper or easier way to meet its<br />

1 UNEP (2008)<br />

2 Boyd et al. (2008)<br />

3 Boyd, Hultman, Roberts, et al. (2007); Wara (2006); Yamin (2005)<br />

4 Reece, Phylipsen, Rathmann, et al. (2006)<br />

5 Halsnæs (1996); Hepburn (2007);); Woerdman (2000)<br />

48<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


obligations. The assumptions are those of trade<br />

in general – that trade allows <strong>for</strong> specialisation<br />

and comparative advantage – and that the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

is there<strong>for</strong>e trade in a commodity that may be<br />

cheaper in the global south. From this economic<br />

perspective, any constraint on the use of the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> would be a barrier to free trade and would<br />

prevent the rational use of resources. However, <strong>for</strong><br />

those critical of trade – who see it as an unequal<br />

power game <strong>for</strong> example – this rational economic<br />

argument <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong> is unacceptable. 6<br />

Another critique of rational choice economics<br />

is that choices are rarely rational because of<br />

incomplete in<strong>for</strong>mation and political, economic,<br />

psychological and cultural constraints.<br />

A second economic issue relevant to the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

is the controversy over the spread of market<br />

environmentalism – the concept that the best<br />

way to manage the environment is to allocate<br />

property rights to nature (<strong>including</strong> climate<br />

and carbon emissions) and to realise its value<br />

through the market and private ownership.<br />

According to this perspective, those who value<br />

environmental protection and the benefits of<br />

a stable climate or clean water will be willing<br />

to pay <strong>for</strong> these ‘environmental services’. A<br />

significant number of environmental scientists<br />

and conservation organisations have seen the<br />

market as the most viable way to obtain funds<br />

to protect ecosystems. 7 Thus carbon trading is<br />

seen as a market environmentalist response to<br />

the risks of climate change – rights or permits<br />

to pollute the atmosphere are assigned (or<br />

auctioned), a cap on emissions is established<br />

to drive demand, and the market is used to<br />

buy and sell excess or needed emission credits.<br />

Critics of market environmentalism have turned<br />

their attention to the carbon markets and the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>, variously arguing that the atmosphere is<br />

a common property resource that should not<br />

be privatised (even if only as a pollutant dump);<br />

that emissions rights have been unequally<br />

distributed (on the basis of prior pollution<br />

rather than a more equitable basis); that the true<br />

values of nature, <strong>including</strong> climate damages, are<br />

unquantifiable and unpriceable; that profits in<br />

an unregulated market can flow to unscrupulous<br />

‘cowboy capitalists’; and that private ownership<br />

is an undemocratic way to manage nature. 8<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong> and the carbon cycle<br />

Earth system science would understand the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

as part of the carbon and other global cycles,<br />

contributing to reductions in greenhouse gases<br />

within the uni<strong>for</strong>mly mixed global atmosphere.<br />

For earth scientists, the primary metric of<br />

success <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong> and other climate policies is<br />

the overall additional and measurable impact on<br />

greenhouse gas concentrations. 9 By seeing the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> as part of the carbon cycle, earth science<br />

draws attention to the multiple opportunities to<br />

intervene in the system – by managing <strong>for</strong>ests<br />

and soils, by capping fossil fuel and cement<br />

emissions, and by <strong>including</strong> the full range of<br />

greenhouse gases – but also to the tremendous<br />

uncertainties associated with measurement,<br />

interannual and spatial variability, permanence<br />

and leakage. In terms of reducing the risks of<br />

dangerous climate change, earth scientists<br />

such as James Hansen argue <strong>for</strong> much stronger<br />

regulation of fossil fuels (<strong>including</strong> a ban on coal<br />

in some cases) and might oppose carbon trading<br />

and the <strong>CDM</strong> on the grounds that, in contrast<br />

to strict caps on emissions from all countries,<br />

trading has delayed the necessary cuts and made<br />

only modest contributions to date.<br />

6 Emmanuel and Bettelheim (1972);<br />

7 Daily and Ellison (2002);<br />

8 Bachram (2004)<br />

9 Field and Raupach (2004); Steffen, Noble, Canadell, et al. (1998)<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong>, ethics and development<br />

49<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


The <strong>CDM</strong> and theories of<br />

technology innovation<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong> is often promoted as a way of transferring<br />

low-carbon technologies to the developing<br />

world, and in the case of proposals <strong>for</strong><br />

sectoral <strong>CDM</strong>, <strong>for</strong> diverting whole economic<br />

sectors into more efficient and less fossil fuelintensive<br />

development paths. Because a wide<br />

range of technologies are approved and proposed<br />

<strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong>, advocates and critics of its role in<br />

technology innovation argue from several different<br />

perspectives. 10 Advocates of the <strong>CDM</strong> draw on<br />

theories of innovation and energy transitions to<br />

argue that it can help to spark innovation in the<br />

developing world, but it is also possible that, by<br />

displacing carbon reductions to the developing<br />

world, the <strong>CDM</strong> reduces pressure <strong>for</strong> domestic<br />

low-carbon technologies in the north and lowers<br />

the price signal that drives innovation. Scholars<br />

who see technology choice as purely a matter of<br />

economics or technical effectiveness in reducing<br />

greenhouse gas emissions might argue that a<br />

broad range of lower carbon technologies should<br />

be included in the <strong>CDM</strong>, <strong>including</strong> nuclear and<br />

carbon sequestration and storage (CCS), whereas<br />

others concerned with risk, public perception<br />

or sustainable development issues would argue<br />

that not only nuclear should be excluded on the<br />

grounds of risk and perceptions, but also HFC<br />

capture because of questionable development<br />

and innovation value. Another perspective<br />

on technology and the <strong>CDM</strong> derives from the<br />

science and technology studies (STS) literature,<br />

which argues that technologies are not neutral<br />

but embody particular social and environmental<br />

relations, often promoted through specific<br />

discourses (e.g. narratives) and governmentalities<br />

(e.g. regulations, monitoring systems). 11 In this<br />

case, the proposals <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> methodologies <strong>for</strong><br />

woodstoves would come with a set of narratives<br />

about appropriate technology, poverty, gender<br />

and conservation, whereas those <strong>for</strong> large-scale<br />

wind or methane capture would carry messages<br />

about industrial development.<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong> and international relations<br />

From an international relations perspective, the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> can be viewed as a north-south bargain<br />

that is critical to the success of the international<br />

climate regime because it has provided a way to<br />

reduce emissions in the south and to include the<br />

developing world in the carbon markets, while<br />

avoiding binding emissions reductions that were<br />

politically unacceptable to most developing<br />

countries. However, political theorists might<br />

differ substantially in their analysis of this<br />

bargain. Traditional state-centred approaches<br />

are uncom<strong>for</strong>table with international agreements<br />

like the <strong>CDM</strong>, which has such heavy involvement<br />

of private, non-state actors. Political economists<br />

see the <strong>CDM</strong> through the lens of a world system<br />

in which powerful interests and countries control<br />

international relations to ensure the smooth<br />

functioning of their economies, and they would<br />

suggest that the <strong>CDM</strong> was designed to serve the<br />

needs of capital by providing cheap emission<br />

reductions, that it has a neo-colonial character or<br />

that it is biased to the interests of more powerful<br />

developed and developing countries such as<br />

China. Another perspective is that global regimes<br />

such as the <strong>CDM</strong> overlook particular national<br />

and cultural conditions, <strong>including</strong> human rights,<br />

property institutions, government systems, and<br />

views of nature. 12<br />

10 Grubb (2004); Dechezleprêtre, Glachant and Ménière (2008);<br />

Schneider, Holzer and Hoffmann (2008)<br />

11 Backstrand and Lovbrand (2006); Oels (2005)<br />

12 Weber (2001)<br />

50<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Ethics and the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Philosophical perspectives on climate policy<br />

have traditionally focused on issues of ethics and<br />

justice, but have not <strong>for</strong> the most part directly<br />

addressed the <strong>CDM</strong>. 13 In terms of ethics, the<br />

popular critique of offsets as indulgences has<br />

some roots in ethical discussions because the<br />

fundamental objection is that paying someone<br />

else to reduce emissions rather than reducing<br />

them yourself is unethical. 14 Such ethical<br />

criticisms are of concern to corporations who<br />

seek to purchase <strong>CDM</strong> credits but at the same<br />

time are worried about the views of consumers,<br />

shareholders and the media. They seek a strong<br />

ethical defence of offsets and the <strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong> their<br />

corporate social responsibility reports. There are<br />

also human rights-based arguments that can be<br />

applied to the <strong>CDM</strong>, especially in cases where the<br />

privatisation of carbon is seen to encroach on the<br />

rights of local people to land or when people are<br />

not included in decision-making about projects. 15<br />

The latter is an example of theories of procedural<br />

justice – where the questions of who is involved in<br />

decisions are important – and can be contrasted<br />

with the numerous questions of distributive<br />

justice raised by the <strong>CDM</strong>. Distributive justice<br />

arguments emerge in the many commentaries<br />

on the unequal pattern of <strong>CDM</strong> projects – with<br />

a bias to larger developing countries such as<br />

India, China and Brazil and to certain gases and<br />

technologies – and in the distribution of local<br />

costs and benefits of projects. An alternative<br />

ethical position is that it is selfish to invest in<br />

expensive domestic emissions reductions when<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> provides faster options <strong>for</strong> reducing<br />

climate risks, as well as side benefits to the poor<br />

in terms of cheaper energy, jobs, or health.<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong> and development<br />

Some of the most persistent criticisms of the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

have focused on its failure to alleviate poverty<br />

and provide local sustainable development<br />

benefits. 16 Although <strong>CDM</strong> is technically not an<br />

external development intervention, nor are <strong>CDM</strong><br />

projects structured like a typical aid project,<br />

development theorists are still likely to see the<br />

The economic argument <strong>for</strong> offsets and the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

is that greenhouse gases are externalities that<br />

can be addressed through regulation, taxation,<br />

and/or trading, and that emission reductions<br />

are cheaper and faster in the developing world<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> and other emissions reductions projects as<br />

a standard development project with financing<br />

from the north <strong>for</strong> technology in the south. One<br />

need only look at the 544 small-scale registered<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> projects to see how they might be linked to<br />

pressing local development priorities in the Global<br />

South. 17 International development agencies and<br />

banks have purposefully driven a campaign <strong>for</strong><br />

‘carbon with a human face’ in ef<strong>for</strong>ts to address<br />

poverty alleviation and technology transfer by<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong>. The World Bank, <strong>for</strong> example, was<br />

one of the first players to actively create several<br />

carbon finance funds <strong>for</strong> development in the<br />

early days of <strong>CDM</strong> development (over the longterm,<br />

financial flows from the <strong>CDM</strong> could reach<br />

up to US$50 million compared to current ODA<br />

flows, which are around US$100 million 18 ). These<br />

estimated financial flows to the Global South<br />

raise <strong>new</strong> questions about how <strong>CDM</strong> finance<br />

13 Adger, Huq, Mace, Paavola (2005);<br />

14 Smith (2007)<br />

15 Bond and Dada (2004)<br />

16 Olsen (2007)<br />

17 Michaelowa and Michaelowa (2007)<br />

18 World Bank (2006)<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong>, ethics and development<br />

51<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


complements or compromises existing aid flows<br />

in unanticipated ways. Some onlookers are<br />

concerned that in the early <strong>CDM</strong> gold rush the<br />

social development dimensions of this ‘complex’<br />

development mechanism gained limited attention.<br />

The heady days when buyers and investors<br />

From an international relations perspective,<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> can be viewed as a north-south<br />

bargain that is critical to the success of the<br />

international climate regime because it has<br />

provided a way to reduce emissions in the<br />

south and to include the developing world in<br />

the carbon markets, while avoiding binding<br />

emissions reductions that were politically<br />

unacceptable to most developing countries.<br />

bought anything they could get their hands on<br />

are over, and investors are looking <strong>for</strong> a re<strong>for</strong>med<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> that includes quality projects that provide<br />

social development. The extensive knowledge<br />

requirements and transactions costs across layers<br />

of administrative scales have unavoidably led to<br />

accountability and transparency challenges that<br />

require re<strong>for</strong>m to ensure the effective delivery of<br />

benefits to local stakeholders. 19<br />

The jury is still out on whether the <strong>CDM</strong> can<br />

deliver to the poor. What is known to date is<br />

that the <strong>CDM</strong> has primarily delivered large-scale<br />

industrial projects in two regions of the world,<br />

at times implemented without local consent<br />

or without factoring in stronger participatory<br />

mechanisms. <strong>CDM</strong> has been weak on addressing<br />

resource access or multiple objectives in <strong>for</strong>est-<br />

based pilot carbon offsets, and financially it has<br />

benefited the developers and designers of <strong>CDM</strong><br />

projects. 20<br />

These early findings of <strong>CDM</strong> social impacts<br />

perhaps also fit in with various expectations<br />

that people have of failed environmentdevelopment-related<br />

initiatives and schemes.<br />

Many of the critical development perspectives<br />

on the <strong>CDM</strong> are influenced by major debates<br />

over previous development interventions.<br />

The three archetypical stories that are widely<br />

discussed in the literature are the Green<br />

Revolution in agriculture, the building of largescale<br />

dam infrastructure, and the promotion of<br />

conservation and protected areas. These stories<br />

relate insights <strong>for</strong> a more nuanced understanding<br />

of the governance and consequences of <strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

development. We devote the rest of this paper to<br />

discussing these stories and showing how they<br />

cast light on current challenges encountered in<br />

delivering pro-poor <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

Development perspectives and the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

There are widely different perspectives on<br />

development, <strong>including</strong> modernisation theory<br />

(an evolutionary approach that saw traditional<br />

societies progress through stages of development<br />

towards a modern economy) and flows of finance<br />

and technology from north to south accelerating<br />

this process and dependency theory (where<br />

wealthy nations make poorer nations dependent<br />

on them through colonialism, unequal terms<br />

of trade, debt, and control of international<br />

relations). Other development theorists see many<br />

development projects as misguided interventions<br />

that take little account of local conditions and<br />

wishes, use inappropriate technologies, and often<br />

19 Muller (2007)<br />

20 Boyd, Gutierrez and Chang (2007); Wara (2007) Lohmann (2006)<br />

52<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


provide unequal benefits within communities. 21<br />

A positive modernising development perspective<br />

on the <strong>CDM</strong> sees offset projects as providing<br />

multiple benefits to local communities, <strong>including</strong><br />

direct revenue, jobs, cheaper and healthier<br />

energy, and biodiversity protection. <strong>CDM</strong><br />

projects might contribute to the alleviation of<br />

poverty and the general improvement in rural<br />

livelihoods. Dependency and other critical<br />

theorists would highlight the ways in which the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> benefits the north more than the south,<br />

is controlled by northern interests and finance,<br />

introduces inappropriate technologies, and<br />

fosters inequality within communities.<br />

(i) Knowledge politics and the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Technology transfer is central to the future of<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> and will depend on the type of technology<br />

transfer, technology choices and investment<br />

decisions of governments and corporations. A<br />

knowledge politics lens explains how misguided<br />

development results from poor understanding of<br />

context and place. 22 The underpinning argument<br />

is that unequal power relations exist between<br />

those who possess technical knowledge and those<br />

who do not, and that this difference disadvantages<br />

local stakeholders in important decision-making<br />

processes that affect their livelihoods. This lens<br />

has been used to explain the negative social<br />

consequences of <strong>CDM</strong> projects in India. 23<br />

The development community has many examples<br />

of knowledge and technology transfer to the Global<br />

South. One such example is the Green Revolution<br />

– a response to famine in India and other regions<br />

of the developing world. With assistance from US<br />

aid organizations and international scientists,<br />

a program began of plant-breeding, irrigation<br />

development and agrochemical financing – a<br />

package of technologies designed to increase<br />

crop yields. This revolution has contributed<br />

to raising Asian per capita food production by<br />

27% and making India food self-sufficient to<br />

the extent that ‘no one sleeps with an empty<br />

belly’, but it has also come under a great deal<br />

of scrutiny. In particular, failures to prioritize<br />

agrarian re<strong>for</strong>m over technological solutions<br />

have lead to poor people being locked into rural<br />

debt by having to purchase inputs. Success has<br />

largely been dependent on access to credit and<br />

land. On the environmental impacts, there has<br />

been a reduction in agricultural diversity and<br />

biodiversity due to a reliance on a few highyield<br />

crops and the expansion of agricultural<br />

monocrops. Subsidy programs have contributed<br />

to the inappropriate use of inputs and the<br />

resource degradation that could be contributing<br />

to the declining rates of growth in crop yields. 24<br />

The Green Revolution was seen to increase<br />

inequality in communities as the better off gained<br />

access to the <strong>new</strong> projects and the poorest were<br />

excluded and as women were excluded from<br />

training and other benefits and struggled with<br />

the ecological impacts of inputs, fertilizers and<br />

loss of biodiversity. 25 The Green Revolution<br />

has polarized the western environmental lobby,<br />

scientists and policy-makers in the Global South.<br />

Western NGOs have been accused of taking<br />

a ‘elitist’ view of poverty in the Global South,<br />

yet more recently, scientists acknowledge that<br />

some billion people are still undernourished<br />

and lack food security and are calling <strong>for</strong> a<br />

second revolution as a response. 26 The <strong>CDM</strong><br />

has some parallels to the Green Revolution in<br />

the transfer of technologies to poor households,<br />

21 Willis (2005)<br />

22 Fairhead and Leach (1995)<br />

23 Lohmann (2008)<br />

24 Wichelns (2004)<br />

25 Sobha (2007)<br />

26 Lynch (2007)<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong>, ethics and development<br />

53<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


the need <strong>for</strong> technical knowledge and assistance<br />

to implement successful emissions reductions,<br />

and the potential to create social and gender<br />

inequalities.<br />

(ii) Stakeholder accountability and the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Although not an intervention per se, as a project<br />

vehicle the <strong>CDM</strong> struggles with inconsistencies<br />

between the idea connected with pro-poor <strong>CDM</strong><br />

that it is supposed to include consultation with<br />

local people and the actual practices of delivery.<br />

Accountability perspectives in development<br />

highlight the need <strong>for</strong> transparent and<br />

legitimate standards, procedures and stakeholder<br />

engagement in development planning and the<br />

execution of development projects. One of the<br />

most controversial experiences of the development<br />

community concerning accountability has been<br />

the experience with the construction of large<br />

dams and water management projects. Between<br />

1950 and 1990, the World Bank and other<br />

development agencies focused finance on the<br />

construction of large infrastructural projects<br />

in the Global South, <strong>including</strong> numerous large<br />

dams such as the Volta, Aswan and Three Gorges.<br />

Among the many criticisms of these large projects<br />

was the lack of consultation of local people, who<br />

were often relocated and whose livelihoods were<br />

affected by the dams and reservoirs. 27 In response,<br />

in 2000 the World Commission on Dams<br />

delivered a report that called <strong>for</strong> the screening of<br />

large projects and transparency in dam-related<br />

decision-making processes. 28 Scholars have noted<br />

the importance of consensus-building among<br />

those impacted by the construction of big dams<br />

and are urging that greater emphasis be placed<br />

on the way that peoples’ values, expectations and<br />

political allegiances change over the lifetime of a<br />

dam project in order to identify which important<br />

assumptions are built into the stakeholder<br />

structures, and the types of knowledge that exist<br />

between experts and lay persons. 29 While the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

community turns to consider broad governance<br />

re<strong>for</strong>ms to the operational procedures <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>CDM</strong> validation and verification, the issue of<br />

accountability regarding social sustainability<br />

remains a challenging one, and there may be<br />

lessons to learn from the experience of large<br />

dams. This is particularly the case in contexts<br />

where there are discrepancies between national<br />

sustainable development criteria, validation and<br />

project implementation.<br />

(iii) Rights-based <strong>for</strong>est<br />

perspectives and the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

The final example of the legacies of previous<br />

development experiences is that of prior attempts<br />

at <strong>for</strong>est conservation and its implications <strong>for</strong> any<br />

consideration of <strong>for</strong>estry within the <strong>CDM</strong>. Any<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project in the land use and <strong>for</strong>est sector<br />

is likely to encounter methodological challenges<br />

in establishing baselines proving additionality<br />

and leakage, as well as in how to ensure a<br />

functioning long-term institutional governance<br />

framework. A long tradition of research in <strong>for</strong>est<br />

governance has revealed numerous problems<br />

with <strong>for</strong>est projects being driven by northern<br />

interests or implemented with insufficient<br />

attention to local ecology, culture and land<br />

rights. 30 Rights-based perspectives draw insights<br />

from other <strong>for</strong>est initiatives, in particular<br />

Integrated Conservation and Development<br />

Projects (ICDP). ICDPs emerged in the 1980s<br />

and were specifically aimed at tackling nonparticipatory<br />

approaches to conserving national<br />

parks. The number of ICDPs rose from 20 in the<br />

27 Goldsmith and Hildyard (1985)<br />

28 World Commission on Dams (2000)<br />

29 Lockie (2007)<br />

30 Gibson, McKean and Ostrom (2000);<br />

54<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


1980s to 300 in the early 2000s. They are also<br />

known as community-based natural resource<br />

management (CBNRM) and are often concerned<br />

with providing employment by ecotourism and<br />

sustainable livelihood alternatives. Above all,<br />

these schemes aim to avoid the threat of local<br />

development on biodiversity conservation.<br />

However, ICDPs have struggled to gain credibility<br />

due to predefined (mostly scientific) external<br />

priorities set by conservation organisations and<br />

national governments, alongside the exclusion of<br />

minorities such as women and landless. It is often<br />

the case that unpopular agricultural options are<br />

provided where local people want cattle and<br />

credit to build up capital. The costs and risks<br />

of engaging in local development, such as land<br />

tenure planning, can be time consuming and<br />

off-putting <strong>for</strong> some conservation organisations.<br />

A recent evaluation of community-based<br />

<strong>for</strong>est management in Nepal shows that poor<br />

communities still gained little from a long-term<br />

programme funded by Australian aid finance. 31<br />

Similarly, some show that, without gaining a clear<br />

understanding of intra-community dynamics and<br />

of community members’ perceptions of external<br />

groups, the design of appropriate strategies <strong>for</strong><br />

collaboration in <strong>for</strong>est management is likely to<br />

fail. 32 Recently findings suggest that conservation<br />

and development programs can positively affect<br />

people if they mainstream outreach ef<strong>for</strong>ts that<br />

address the particular localized manifestations of<br />

health problems such as HIV/AIDS in the context<br />

of natural resource management. 33 In revisiting<br />

<strong>for</strong>ests and land-use change under a post-2012<br />

agreement, the rights-based perspective is<br />

certain to be present. Already discussions on<br />

Reduced Emissions from Avoided De<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

31 Thoms (2008)<br />

32 Horowitz (2008)<br />

have sparked a response from civil society<br />

regarding the negative impacts of REDD projects<br />

on local peoples.<br />

Can the <strong>CDM</strong> respond?<br />

How may an improved <strong>CDM</strong> satisfy the critics as<br />

outlined in the six perspectives? While important<br />

lessons can be drawn from previous experiences<br />

in development, the range of perspectives<br />

discussed in the first part of the paper means<br />

that it is well nigh impossible <strong>for</strong> a re<strong>for</strong>med <strong>CDM</strong><br />

to satisfy some of its critics, especially where<br />

scholars have very different and deeply rooted<br />

views of economics, ethics or the structure of<br />

In terms of ethics, the popular critique of<br />

offsets as indulgences has some roots in ethical<br />

discussions because the fundamental objection<br />

is that paying someone else to reduce emissions<br />

rather than reducing them yourself is unethical<br />

international relations. For earth scientists, a<br />

re<strong>for</strong>med <strong>CDM</strong> would need to ensure additional<br />

and significant interventions in the carbon cycle<br />

so as to reduce the risks of climate change more<br />

rapidly, perhaps <strong>including</strong> a broader range of<br />

greenhouse gases. Economists focused on the<br />

most efficient <strong>CDM</strong> might propose dropping<br />

the sustainable development criteria in favour<br />

of a focus on carbon alone. Some theorists of<br />

technology innovation might prefer sectoral<br />

and policy <strong>CDM</strong> that would promote largescale<br />

sociotechnical transitions. Ethical debates<br />

might clarify decisions about the proportion of<br />

emissions reduction obligations that should be<br />

made through offsets.<br />

33 Demotts (2008)<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong>, ethics and development<br />

55<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Development theorists might propose a <strong>CDM</strong><br />

which gives greater weighting to poorer countries<br />

and ensures a more equitable participation and<br />

distribution of benefits within communities.<br />

As <strong>CDM</strong> moves from the frontiers of the ‘wild<br />

west’ to a mature market, the focus of market<br />

players is shifting increasingly towards highquality<br />

CERS with sustainability co-benefits as<br />

criteria. <strong>CDM</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m includes the <strong>new</strong> kid on<br />

the block – Programmes of Activities (PoAs).<br />

These integrated and scaled-up projects open<br />

up hope <strong>for</strong> <strong>new</strong> opportunities <strong>for</strong> small-scale<br />

projects and should in theory act as an incentive<br />

<strong>for</strong> the delivery of sustainable development to<br />

low-income communities. Examples include<br />

rural lighting in India, energy retrofitting and<br />

small community waste treatments. Although<br />

Programmes of Activities are creative, they<br />

are presently confronted with a multitude of<br />

challenges, such as unclear methodologies and<br />

sampling norms, EB discrepancies and reluctant<br />

validators. The development perspectives in this<br />

essay illustrate that the <strong>CDM</strong> community faces<br />

the dual challenges of accommodating plural<br />

perspectives and practical operational issues. One<br />

of the most important tests <strong>for</strong> the community<br />

will be to avoid polarisations around <strong>CDM</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

and keep the process moving <strong>for</strong>ward.<br />

As yet we do not have this accumulated body<br />

of work on the <strong>CDM</strong>, and careful comparative<br />

and data rich studies are needed to understand<br />

under what conditions the <strong>CDM</strong> contributes to<br />

sustainable development and rapid emissions<br />

reductions.<br />

Diana Liverman is the Director of Ox<strong>for</strong>d University’s<br />

Environmental Change Institute, coordinating work in climate,<br />

energy and ecosystems with a strong applied and policy focus<br />

that includes the UK Climate Impacts Programme, the Tyndall<br />

Centre and UK Energy Research Centre.<br />

Contact: diana.liverman@eci.ox.ac.uk<br />

Emily Boyd is a post-doctoral fellow at the Environmental<br />

Change Institute and senior researcher at the Stockholm<br />

Resilience Centre, Stockholm University. She specializes in<br />

climate change and international development with current<br />

research focused on carbon markets and development in India.<br />

Contact: emily.boyd@ouce.ox.ac.uk<br />

In this paper, we have discussed some of the<br />

underlying theoretical and political perspectives<br />

that may underpin debates about the <strong>CDM</strong> and<br />

have shown how past experiences of environment<br />

and development may foster scepticism about<br />

the sustainable development benefits. It is,<br />

however, important to note that the theoretical<br />

critique and evaluation of large dams, the<br />

Green Revolution and conservation projects<br />

are supported by several decades of careful<br />

empirical studies that have included fieldwork<br />

by independent researchers to understand under<br />

what conditions these projects succeed and fail.<br />

56<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


References<br />

Adger, W., Huq, S., Mace, M. and Paavola, J. 2005. Equity and Justice in<br />

Adaptation to Climate Change. MIT Press, Cambridge.<br />

Bachram, H. 2004. Climate fraud and carbon colonialism: the <strong>new</strong> trade in<br />

greenhouse gases. Capitalism Nature Socialism. 15(4):5-20.<br />

Backstrand, K. and Lovbrand, E. 2006. Planting Trees to Mitigate Climate<br />

Change: Contested Discourses of Ecological Modernization, Green Governmentality<br />

and Civic Environmentalism. Global Environmental Politics.<br />

6(1):50-75.<br />

Bond, P. and Dada, R., ed. 2004. Trouble in the Air: Global Warming and<br />

the Privatised Atmosphere. Durban SA: Center <strong>for</strong> Civil Society.<br />

Boyd, E., Gutierrez, M. and Chang, M. 2007. Small-scale <strong>for</strong>est carbon<br />

projects: adapting <strong>CDM</strong> to low-income communities. Global Environmental<br />

Change. 17(2):250-259.<br />

Boyd, E., Hultman, N., et al. 2008. Re<strong>for</strong>ming the <strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong> sustainable<br />

development: lessons learned and policy futures. Environmental Science<br />

and Policy. (under revision).<br />

Boyd, E., Hultman, N., Roberts, T., Corbera, E., Ebeling, J., Liverman,<br />

D., Brown, K., Tippmann, R., Cole, J. and Mann, P. 2007. The Clean<br />

Development Mechanism: an assessment of current practice and future<br />

approaches <strong>for</strong> policy. Tyndall Working Paper. Environmental Change<br />

Institute Ox<strong>for</strong>d, Tyndall Centre <strong>for</strong> Climate Change Research in cooperation<br />

with EcoSecurities. http://www.tyndall.ac.uk/publications/working_papers/twp114.pdf<br />

Daily, G. C. and Ellison, K. 2002. The New Economy of Nature: The Quest<br />

to Make Conservation Profitable. Island Press.<br />

Dechezleprêtre, A., Glachant, M. and Ménière, Y. 2008. The Clean Development<br />

Mechanism and the international diffusion of technologies: An<br />

empirical study. Energy Policy. 36(4):1273-1283.<br />

Emmanuel, A. and Bettelheim, C. 1972. Unequal exchange: a study of the<br />

imperialism of trade. Monthly Review Press.<br />

Fairhead, J., and Leach, M. 1995. False <strong>for</strong>est history, complicit social<br />

analysis: rethinking some West African environmental narratives. World<br />

Development Vol. 23:6 (1023-1035).<br />

Field, C. and Raupach, M. 2004. The Global Carbon Cycle: Integrating<br />

Humans, Climate, and the Natural World. Island Press.<br />

Gibson, C., McKean, M. and Ostrom, E. 2000. People and Forests: Communities,<br />

Institutions, and Governance. MIT Press.<br />

Goldsmith, E. and Hildyard, N. 1985. The Social and Environmental Effects<br />

of Large Dams. San Francisco (USA): Sierra Club Books.<br />

Grubb, M. 2004. Technology Innovation and Climate Change Policy: An<br />

Overview of Issues and Options. Keio Economics Studies. 41(2):103.<br />

Halsnæs, K. 1996. The economics of climate change mitigation in developing<br />

countries. Energy Policy. 24(10-11):917-926.<br />

Hepburn, C. 2007. Carbon Trading: A Review of the Kyoto <strong>Mechanisms</strong>.<br />

Annual Review of Environment and Resources 32(375).<br />

Horowitz, L.S. 2008. “It’s up to the clan to protect”: cultural heritage and<br />

the micropolitical ecology of conservation in New Caledonia. Social Science<br />

Journal. Vol. 45: 2, 258-278.<br />

Lockie, S. 2007. Deliberation and actor-networks: the “practical’’ implications<br />

of social theory <strong>for</strong> the assessment of large dams and other interventions.<br />

Society and Natural Resources. Vol.20: 9, 785-799.<br />

Lohmann, L. 2006. Carbon trading: a critical conversation on climate<br />

change, privatisation and power. Uppsala Dag Hammarskjöld Foundation.<br />

Lynch, JP. 2007. Roots of the second green revolution. Australian Journal<br />

of Botany. Vol. 55: 5, 493-512<br />

Michaelowa, K and Michaelowa, A. 2007. Special Issue: Climate or Development?<br />

Climatic Change. Vol. 84:1, pp. 1-111.<br />

Muller, A. 2007. How to make the clean development mechanism sustainable:<br />

the potential of rent extraction. Energy Policy. 35(6):3203-3212.<br />

Oels, A. 2005. Rendering climate change governable: from biopower to<br />

advanced liberal government? Journal of Environmental Policy & Planning.<br />

7(3):185-207.<br />

Olsen, K. 2007. The clean development mechanism’s contribution to<br />

sustainable development: a review of the literature. Climatic Change.<br />

84(1):59-73.<br />

Reece, G., Phylipsen, D., Rathmann, M., Horstink, M. and Angelini, T.<br />

2006. Use of JI/<strong>CDM</strong> credits by participants in phase II of the EU ETS.<br />

London: ECOFYS. http://www.wwf.org.uk/filelibrary/pdf/ecofys_271006_<br />

report.pdf<br />

Schneider, M., Holzer, A. and Hoffmann, V. H. 2008. Understanding the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>’s contribution to technology transfer. Energy Policy. 36(8):2930-<br />

2938.<br />

Smith, K. 2007. The Carbon Neutral Myth-Offset Indulgences <strong>for</strong> your<br />

Climate Sins. http://www.carbontradewatch.org/pubs/carbon_neutral_myth.pdf<br />

Sobha, I. 2007. Green Revolution: Impact on Gender. Journal of Human<br />

Ecology. Vol 22:2, 107-113.<br />

Steffen, W., Noble, I., Canadell, J., Apps, M., Schulze, E., Jarvis, P., Baldocchi,<br />

D., Ciais, P., Cramer, W. and Ehleringer, J. 1998. The terrestrial carbon<br />

cycle: implications <strong>for</strong> the Kyoto Protocol. Science. 280(5368):1393-<br />

1394.<br />

Thoms C.A. 2008. Community control of resources and the challenge of<br />

improving local livelihoods: a critical examination of community <strong>for</strong>estry in<br />

Nepal. Geo<strong>for</strong>um. Vol. 39: 3, 1452-1465.<br />

UNEP. 2008. Risoe <strong>CDM</strong>/JI Pipeline Analysis and Database, October 1st<br />

2008<br />

Wara, M. 2006. Measuring the Clean Development Mechanism’s<br />

Per<strong>for</strong>mance and Potential. Stan<strong>for</strong>d University, Program on Energy and<br />

Sustainable Development, Working Paper. http://iis-db.stan<strong>for</strong>d.edu/<br />

pubs/21211/Wara_<strong>CDM</strong>.pdf<br />

Wara, M. 2007. Is the global carbon market working? Nature.<br />

445(7128):595.<br />

Weber, C. 2001. International Relations Theory: A Critical Introduction.<br />

Routledge.<br />

Wichelns, D. 2004. The impact of public policies on the sustainability<br />

of rice and wheat production on the Indo-Gangetic plains. Journal of<br />

Sustainable Agriculture. Vol. 23:3, 67-92.<br />

Willis, K. 2005. Theories and Practices of Development. Routledge.<br />

Woerdman, E. 2000. Implementing the Kyoto protocol: why JI and <strong>CDM</strong><br />

show more promise than international emissions trading. Energy Policy.<br />

28(1):29-38.<br />

World Bank 2006. State of the Carbon Market. Washington: World Bank.<br />

World Commission on Dams 2000. Dams and Development: A New<br />

Framework <strong>for</strong> Decision Making. http://www.dams.org/<br />

Yamin, F. 2005. Climate Change and Carbon Markets: A Handbook of<br />

Emission Reduction <strong>Mechanisms</strong>. Earthscan.<br />

Lohmann, L. 2008. Carbon Trading, Climate Justice and the Production of<br />

Ignorance: Ten Examples. Development. 51(3):359-365.<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong>, ethics and development<br />

57<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


58<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Hans Jürgen Stehr<br />

Danish Commission on Climate Change Policy<br />

Does the <strong>CDM</strong> need an<br />

institutional re<strong>for</strong>m?<br />

Abstract:<br />

This article deals with the present projectbased<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> from a governance perspective.<br />

In terms of volume and numbers, the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

seems to have met the expectations of the<br />

political system. The question is whether it is<br />

sufficiently adapted to this success and potential<br />

expansion. A number of private stakeholder<br />

suggestions and options presently discussed<br />

by government representatives preparing <strong>for</strong><br />

COP 15 are analysed. The article identifies as<br />

an important issue that powers, which in other<br />

regulatory systems would typically be divided,<br />

are concentrated at the Executive Board level in<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> system. In conclusion, it is suggested -<br />

as a package - to move towards more top-down<br />

standardization of methodologies, to strengthen<br />

standard setting and supervision of DOEs and, as<br />

an institutional change, to introduce an appeals<br />

system <strong>for</strong> cases of registration and issuance while<br />

at the same time abolishing the review procedures.<br />

This article looks at the Clean Development<br />

Mechanism from a governance perspective. It<br />

will refer to some governance theory but it is not<br />

meant to be scientific, since I am no governance<br />

expert, nor is it meant to solve everything. It attempts<br />

to give some answers to the question how<br />

governance of the <strong>CDM</strong> might be improved and<br />

whether any such improvements might imply institutional<br />

changes.<br />

In creating the <strong>CDM</strong>, the UN system has actually<br />

succeeded in building up the framework <strong>for</strong><br />

a market mechanism that works in spite of its<br />

imperfections and fosters significant financial<br />

flows to environmentally sensitive projects in developing<br />

countries. That in itself comes close to a<br />

miracle. But even miracles can be improved on.<br />

A lot of ef<strong>for</strong>t is continually being made, not least<br />

* the essay represents the authors’ personal views and not necessarily the<br />

position of the Government of China or the National Climate Change<br />

Coordination Committee Secretariat,<br />

59<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


y the Board, in order to trans<strong>for</strong>m the lessons<br />

learned and experience gained into improved<br />

manageability and transparency of the present<br />

system, aiming to ease the ability of the stakeholders<br />

involved to manoeuvre and at the same<br />

time ensure the required environmental integrity.<br />

It has to be born in mind that the <strong>CDM</strong> has<br />

only been fully operational <strong>for</strong> a relatively short<br />

period since the Kyoto Protocol came into <strong>for</strong>ce<br />

in early 2005.<br />

The private sector and other stakeholders have<br />

been very active in providing contributions on<br />

how to improve the system. Some of them are<br />

reflected in this article, as are a number of suggestions<br />

and options presently being discussed<br />

within the framework of the Ad Hoc Working<br />

Group <strong>for</strong> Further Commitments <strong>for</strong> Annex I Parties<br />

under the Kyoto Protocol (AWG KP). 1<br />

The article is based on my personal experience<br />

from having served <strong>for</strong> six years on the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive<br />

Board, on countless <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>mal<br />

discussions with stakeholders, and, hopefully, on<br />

some common sense. The focus will be on the existing<br />

project based <strong>CDM</strong> governance system as<br />

this has developed so far 2 and within that context<br />

on the basic functions of the Executive Board,<br />

this being the core body of the system.<br />

First, the article will define governance and assess<br />

the achievements of the <strong>CDM</strong> in terms of the<br />

number and volume of projects that have been<br />

generated or are under preparation. The powers<br />

granted to the Executive Board and the style<br />

of regulation are then analysed. Based on this<br />

1<br />

1 See the compilation in doc. FCCC/TP/2008/2 sect. III.A (http://<br />

maindb.unfccc.int/library/view_pdf.pl?url=http://unfccc.int/resource/<br />

docs/2008/tp/02.pdf)<br />

2 The article does not deal with suggestions to extend the scope and<br />

scale of the <strong>CDM</strong> into e.g. sectoral concepts, nor does it deal with market<br />

implications as such or suggestions to directly or indirectly influence<br />

market penetration of CERs.<br />

analysis, improvements to the existing governance<br />

system of the <strong>CDM</strong> are discussed. Finally,<br />

the article concludes by suggesting – as a package<br />

– more top-down standardization of methodologies,<br />

strengthened supervision of DOEs and<br />

introduction of an appeal system <strong>for</strong> registration<br />

and issuance cases with, as an institutional<br />

change, an independent appeal body.<br />

2. Governance and the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

The World Bank broadly defines governance as<br />

‘the exercise of political authority and the use of<br />

institutional resources to manage society’s problems<br />

and affairs’. 3 More specifically, governance<br />

relates to decisions that define expectations,<br />

grant power or verify per<strong>for</strong>mance.<br />

The expectations of the political system is that<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> as it is designed will deliver the public<br />

goods expressed in its objectives in the shape of<br />

real, measurable and additional reductions and<br />

the promotion of sustainable development, i.e.<br />

output legitimacy.<br />

Power is granted to institutions by the Kyoto<br />

Conference of Parties (COP/MOP or CMP),<br />

with the Executive Board in a core role and with<br />

Board-accredited validators and verifiers (Designated<br />

Operational Entities, DOEs) and nationally<br />

appointed Designated National Authorities<br />

(DNAs).<br />

The institutions exercise their powers as basically<br />

regulated in the Modalities and Procedures<br />

of Marrakech (who does what) in a certain style<br />

of regulation (how is it done). Taken together,<br />

the institutional framework, the regulatory system<br />

and the style of regulation determine the ef-<br />

3 World Bank 1991, ‘Managing Development: The Governance Dimension’,<br />

Washington D.C.<br />

60<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


ficiency of the system, not least in terms of the<br />

transaction costs involved.<br />

The incentive <strong>for</strong> the private sector to participate<br />

voluntarily is a positive sanction by the system in<br />

the <strong>for</strong>m of the issuance of tradable credits corresponding<br />

to verified reductions (CERs). The<br />

way in which the regulatory system and the style<br />

of regulation represents the roles, interests and<br />

rights of participating stakeholders determines<br />

the input legitimacy.<br />

There is no systematic verification on a qualitative<br />

basis of the per<strong>for</strong>mance of the <strong>CDM</strong> system.<br />

There is, however, broad statistical coverage of<br />

the development of the <strong>CDM</strong>, provided in particular<br />

by UNEP Risø. 4<br />

3. Achievement of expectations so far<br />

The number of projects and the volume of<br />

investments are important although not exclusive<br />

indicators of output legitimacy.<br />

As of 1 September 2008, more than 3800 pro jects<br />

are in the pipeline, 5 <strong>including</strong> 1152 registered<br />

projects. In total up to 2012 they are expected<br />

to yield 1.5 billion CERs. 6 With a price of, <strong>for</strong><br />

example, USD 20 per CER, USD 1.5 billion will<br />

become available <strong>for</strong> adaptation through the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> (2% share of proceeds).<br />

The steady flow of projects entering the pipeline,<br />

in the order of 120 per month, might be seen as<br />

an indicator of continuous private-sector interest<br />

and possibly of confidence in the system as it<br />

has actually been designed and is developing.<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong>, being a bottom-up mechanism, very<br />

much represents a carrot style of regulation.<br />

Another way to assess the success of the <strong>CDM</strong> is<br />

to look at the significant investment flows into<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> projects. According to a 2007 UNFCCC<br />

report on investment and financial flows, the<br />

capital that will be invested in <strong>CDM</strong> projects<br />

registered during 2006 is estimated at about<br />

USD 7 billion. The estimated investment in<br />

re<strong>new</strong>able energy and energy-efficiency projects<br />

of USD 5.7 billion is roughly triple the official<br />

development assistance support <strong>for</strong> energy<br />

policy and re<strong>new</strong>able energy projects in the<br />

same countries. The capital that will be invested<br />

in projects that entered the <strong>CDM</strong> pipeline<br />

during 2006 is estimated at over USD 25 billion.<br />

In comparison, the total investment leveraged<br />

through the Global Environment Facility (GEF)<br />

in the area of climate change since it started is<br />

USD 14 billion. 7<br />

The present and expected volume of the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

does not reflect a corresponding north–south<br />

4 See statistics provided by UNEP Risø http://cdmpipeline.org/<br />

5 This figure should be reduced by approximately 20% to take into account<br />

projects that are expected not to pass validation or to be rejected.<br />

6 The total expected number of CERs accumulated up to 2012 according<br />

to project in<strong>for</strong>mation will be approximately 2.75 billion. The figure<br />

quoted of 1.5 billion takes into account an estimated 40% reduction<br />

due to the reduced number of projects actually registered (cf. previous<br />

footnote) and a some postponing of issuance relative to per<strong>for</strong>mance.<br />

7 For details, see Dialogue working paper 8, paragraph 41. See http://<br />

unfccc.int/files/cooperation_and_support/financial_mechanism/financial_mechanism_gef/application/pdf/dialogue_working_paper_8.pdf<br />

and<br />

the Carbon Markets chapter of the background paper. http://unfccc.int/<br />

files/cooperation_and_support/financial_mechanism/application/pdf/<br />

potential_of_carbon_matkets.pdf<br />

Does the <strong>CDM</strong> need an institutional re<strong>for</strong>m?<br />

61<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


transfer of <strong>new</strong> technology, since many projects<br />

so far have been registered without the involvement<br />

of <strong>for</strong>eign investment other than the purchase<br />

of CERs. The expectations of the political<br />

system – that sustainable development be promoted<br />

– are accommodated merely by definition,<br />

since confirmation thereof is the prerogative of<br />

parties to that same political system (the DNAs).<br />

In summary, it seems that expectations are being<br />

met and that the <strong>CDM</strong> can be considered a success<br />

in terms of numbers and volume and hence in assisting<br />

Annex I to achieve compliance. The question is<br />

whether the governance of the <strong>CDM</strong> and its institutional<br />

set up has been sufficiently adapted to this<br />

success and to a situation where there is a potential<br />

<strong>for</strong> even more projects to pass through its system in<br />

the future.<br />

4. Powers granted to the Executive Board<br />

The Board is super-ordinate within the mandate<br />

given by the CMP in the Modalities & Procedures<br />

(M&Ps) and in subsequent CMP decisions and<br />

guidance. Together with its support structure,<br />

the Board constitutes the centralised level of<br />

the governance system of the <strong>CDM</strong>. The DOEs<br />

act on a decentralised level, but as part of the<br />

centralised decision-making process. The DNAs<br />

exercise their specific national functions on the<br />

decentralised level.<br />

According to the M&Ps, the Executive Board<br />

takes the basic decisions necessary <strong>for</strong> the further<br />

implementation of the system. Hence, it has<br />

regulatory as well as executive functions.<br />

As a regulatory body, the Board adopts material<br />

rules as well as procedural rules.<br />

Material rules are the baseline and monitoring<br />

methodologies that constitute the basic eligibility<br />

requirements, <strong>including</strong> guidance and<br />

clarifications on how methodologies are to be<br />

understood. Methodological tools, such as the<br />

additionality tool, are not binding as such unless<br />

they have been incorporated into an approved<br />

methodology. However, they represent standards<br />

which are accepted by the Board. Thus the Board<br />

provides the conditions to be met in order <strong>for</strong> the<br />

project participans ultimately to achieve CERs.<br />

The procedural rules comprise, e.g., procedures<br />

<strong>for</strong> the approval and revision of methodologies,<br />

the accreditation, supervision etc. of DOEs, the<br />

submission of requests <strong>for</strong> registration and issuance,<br />

the review of such cases and the administration<br />

of the CER registry. In general, the Board<br />

provides procedural rules that govern participation<br />

in the administrative process, communication<br />

top-down and bottom-up, the decision-making<br />

process itself and any administrative review<br />

of decisions.<br />

In its executive function, the Board accredits<br />

DOEs, registers projects on the basis of DOE<br />

validations, issues CERs, governs the CER registry<br />

and decides its own budget and support<br />

structure through the Management Plan (MAP).<br />

Registration and issuance take place automatically<br />

upon submission or request by the DOEs,<br />

unless the Board itself decides to exercise its<br />

right to undertake a review, which will conclude<br />

in final registration or issuance (with or without<br />

corrections) or in final rejection. By deciding to<br />

undertake a review, the Board exercises a quasijudicial<br />

function in the sense that it contests the<br />

assessment of the con<strong>for</strong>mity of the specifics of a<br />

case with the material rules that has been undertaken<br />

by another official body of the decisionmaking<br />

process accredited <strong>for</strong> that function, i.e.<br />

the DOE.<br />

The Board is composed of ten members and ten<br />

alternates, in practical terms working as a team of<br />

twenty, elected in their personal capacity by the<br />

62<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


CMP <strong>for</strong> two-year terms with the possibility of reelection.<br />

They are expected to possess appropriate<br />

technical and/or political expertise. Candidates<br />

are nominated by the regional groups of<br />

the UN system plus by Annex I and non-Annex I<br />

respectively. Thus, of the twenty, twelve are from<br />

developing countries and eight from developed<br />

countries. The chair and vice-chair are, according<br />

to the M&Ps, elected by the Board itself <strong>for</strong><br />

one-year terms alternating between Annex I and<br />

Non-Annex I representatives.<br />

At present, the meeting time alone amounts to<br />

approximately eight weeks per year. In addition,<br />

considerable time is spent preparing <strong>for</strong> meetings,<br />

exercising special functions on the Board<br />

itself or in panels and working groups etc. In its<br />

report to CMP-3, the Board has noted that presently<br />

there is no remuneration or compensation<br />

<strong>for</strong> this dedication of time. 8 The nomination<br />

process and the working conditions favour, in<br />

general terms, the election of government employees,<br />

most of whom belong to their national<br />

negotiation teams.<br />

Since early 2007, the <strong>CDM</strong> has been self-financing<br />

in practice, mainly through shares of the proceeds<br />

of issued CERs (initially paid as registration<br />

fees). This has given the Board control over<br />

resource allocations to the secretariat and over<br />

the development and implementation of an appropriate<br />

support structure. To assist the Board<br />

in accomplishing its tasks, it has set up several<br />

subcommittees or panels (presently the Accreditation<br />

Panel, Methodologies Panel, De<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

& Re<strong>for</strong>estation Working Group and Small-Scale<br />

Working Group) as well as a Registration and Issuance<br />

Team (short RIT). Through the Secretari-<br />

8 Members and alternates are granted a daily subsistence allowance<br />

that is 40% more than the standard UN rate. Cf. decision 7/CMP 1<br />

paragraph 17.<br />

Table 1<br />

Stick, carrot, and sermon styles of regulation.<br />

The stick style of regulation The carrot style of regulation The sermon style of regulation<br />

Regulatory logic Command and control Incentives (mostly economic) In<strong>for</strong>mation and inducement<br />

Role of regulator<br />

Decides and enacts binding<br />

standards and rules<br />

Set out structures of incentives<br />

Provide in<strong>for</strong>mation and encourage<br />

certain actions<br />

Role of regulated<br />

Freedom of choice is delimited<br />

by regulatory acts<br />

Voluntary, calculated choices<br />

based on incentive structures<br />

Voluntary choices subsequent<br />

to the in<strong>for</strong>mation and sermons<br />

available<br />

Strengths<br />

High certainty of compliance<br />

and standardised effects on<br />

regulated actors<br />

Use of regulated actors’<br />

personal utility functions and<br />

knowledge<br />

Use of regulated actors’<br />

personal utility functions and<br />

knowledge<br />

Weaknesses<br />

Potentially rigid, inflexible and<br />

expensive<br />

Uncertainty about effect<br />

caused by reliance on individual<br />

calculus<br />

Source: Ole Helby Petersen 2008: ‘Theorizing on Public-Private Partnerships: Regulatory Regimes, Credible<br />

Commitments and Social Trust’, International Center <strong>for</strong> Business and Politics (working paper).<br />

Uncertainty about effect<br />

caused by reliance on individual<br />

calculus<br />

Does the <strong>CDM</strong> need an institutional re<strong>for</strong>m?<br />

63<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


at, these assist EB members to address validation<br />

and verification issues. The chairs and vice-chairs<br />

of expert panels and working groups are selected<br />

from among Board members and alternates in order<br />

to ensure appropriate interaction.<br />

5. The <strong>CDM</strong> and different<br />

styles of regulation<br />

Regulation is part of any system of governance.<br />

As shown in the following table, generically different<br />

types of regulation have different implications<br />

<strong>for</strong> the roles of the regulator and the regulated<br />

and different strengths and weaknesses.<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong>, being a bottom-up mechanism, very<br />

much represents a carrot style of regulation.<br />

From a broader governance perspective, the stick<br />

style of regulation can be the most efficient and<br />

provide the most output legitimacy. The carrot<br />

style might be less efficient, but on the other<br />

hand it ensures more input legitimacy. The sermon<br />

style might be least efficient but ensures input<br />

legitimacy. Hence, legitimacy and efficiency<br />

concerns are interdependent and at the same<br />

time often in conflict with each other.<br />

6. Improving governance<br />

of the existing <strong>CDM</strong><br />

In this section, some key elements will be<br />

discussed regarding further improvements<br />

to the <strong>CDM</strong> governance system, with a particular<br />

emphasis on the core elements of<br />

the existing <strong>CDM</strong>, i.e. methodologies, accreditation,<br />

and registration and issuance.<br />

The focus will be on the balance between<br />

legitimacy and efficiency.<br />

6.1. Standardizing of methodologies<br />

From the point of view of project developers, it<br />

has been claimed that clarity over rules is an<br />

overarching prerequisite in order to attract investment.<br />

Clarity prevents the risk that projects<br />

will be deemed ineligible or that eligible projects<br />

will receive fewer credits than estimated. Risks<br />

tend to make investment unattractive, especially<br />

since capital needs to be deployed be<strong>for</strong>e actual<br />

approval of registration and issuance. 9<br />

In response, the Board has continually simplified<br />

and clarified various procedures by adapting<br />

them to lessons learned, experience gained<br />

and development of the mechanism in general.<br />

Examples are the extension of the grace period<br />

<strong>for</strong> use of an older version of a revised methodology<br />

to eight months, and the streamlining and<br />

encouragement of interactions between project<br />

developers and the secretariat on methodology<br />

issues. The Board also follows up with frequent<br />

guidance and clarifications. 10<br />

At the same time, the Board has consolidated<br />

a number of methodologies. The consolidated<br />

methodology <strong>for</strong> grid-connected electricity generation<br />

from re<strong>new</strong>able sources, <strong>for</strong> example, covers<br />

technologies or measures such as solar, hydro,<br />

tidal, wave, wind and geothermal, 11 which makes<br />

it the most widely applied methodology, used in<br />

more than 40% of all projects registered.<br />

Also, standardizing methodologies adds to clarity,<br />

and the Board has developed seven generic<br />

tools so far, 12 <strong>including</strong> the additionality tool and<br />

9 Presentation by Forrister at IETA side event on <strong>CDM</strong> at SBs, 11 June<br />

2008.<br />

10 See <strong>for</strong> examples the 2007 EB-report, paragraphs 37, 74 and 83, on<br />

guidance to project developers.<br />

11 ACM0002.<br />

12 The “technical” tools cover calculation of the emissions factor <strong>for</strong><br />

electrical systems, calculation of project- or leakage-related CO2 emissions<br />

from fossil fuel combustion, calculation of project emissions from<br />

electricity consumption, determination of methane emissions avoided<br />

from dumping waste at a solid-waste disposal site, and determination of<br />

project emissions from flaring gases containing methane.<br />

64<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


the combined baseline and additionality tool,<br />

referenced to in more than fifty methodologies.<br />

It is claimed that there is a lingering uncertainty<br />

about additionality, since it leaves it to the project<br />

participant to prove that the project in question<br />

is not a business-as-usual project. The additionality<br />

tool was first issued in October 2004. Since<br />

then it has been developed further by the Board,<br />

as practical experience was gained until the last<br />

update in August 2008. It is generally considered<br />

valid and helpful as top-down guidance.<br />

costs of the validation and verification of such<br />

projects could be exempt from paying a share of<br />

proceeds <strong>for</strong> administration.<br />

In the AWG KP the concern is raised about the<br />

DOEs assessing projects on behalf of the<br />

regulatory system while at the same being<br />

commercially connected to the project developers.<br />

Among the options suggested in the AWG KP,<br />

one is to allow the Board to pre-approve parameters<br />

or procedures to define a (conservative)<br />

standardized baseline <strong>for</strong> certain types of project<br />

activities, e.g. a benchmark or deemed value <strong>for</strong> a<br />

specific energy-consuming appliance or activity.<br />

A list could be established of project activity types<br />

that need or need not demonstrate additionality<br />

individually. A remaining task would be to ensure<br />

that the <strong>CDM</strong> is not applied in the implementation<br />

of policies etc. which would be implemented<br />

anyway. Ways of ensuring this could be to determine<br />

default subtractions of CERs to be issued<br />

or developing dynamic baselines to take into account<br />

the per<strong>for</strong>mance of <strong>CDM</strong> projects already<br />

implemented within that policy framework. 13<br />

In order to promote a more equal geographical<br />

distribution of projects, another option suggested<br />

in the AWG KP is to remove the requirement<br />

to demonstrate additionality <strong>for</strong> small-scale<br />

projects in specific host countries such as Least<br />

Developed Countries (LDCs) and Small Island<br />

Development States (SIDSs). Alternatively the<br />

13 See as an example ACM0013, “Consolidated methodology <strong>for</strong> <strong>new</strong><br />

grid connected fossil fuel fired power plants using a less GHG intensive<br />

technology”. In approving the methodology, the Board noted that the<br />

specifics of the methodology ensured amongst other things that the<br />

potential <strong>for</strong> the application in a particular geographical area would decrease<br />

as more such projects are registered under the <strong>CDM</strong> (EB 34, para.<br />

16 . http://cdm.unfccc.int/EB/034/eb34rep.pdf).<br />

The conclusion to the above seems to be that<br />

project developers prefer even more hierarchy<br />

than is presently provided through voluntary<br />

exchange (sticks instead of carrots). At the same<br />

time, the political system is discussing options<br />

<strong>for</strong> further standardizations and further ways of<br />

simplifying the additionality requirements without<br />

jeopardizing environmental integrity.<br />

Consequently the Board could be <strong>for</strong>mally mandated<br />

to provide top-down methodology tools<br />

and standardization covering, e.g., re<strong>new</strong>able<br />

energy activities, demand-side energy efficiency,<br />

transport, agriculture, af<strong>for</strong>estation and re<strong>for</strong>estation,<br />

and other relevant areas. The CMP has<br />

already asked the Board to continue its ef<strong>for</strong>ts<br />

to broaden the applicability of methodologies. 14<br />

The Board could ask the secretariat to prepare<br />

relevant proposals (which to some extent it does<br />

already), involving external consultants and<br />

project developers organized in a representative<br />

way.<br />

In particular, tools could serve as building blocks<br />

<strong>for</strong> <strong>new</strong> approaches. In parallel, the traditional<br />

bottom-up approach should be maintained, al-<br />

14 Decision 2/CMP.3 para. 18 (b).<br />

Does the <strong>CDM</strong> need an institutional re<strong>for</strong>m?<br />

65<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


lowing <strong>for</strong> <strong>new</strong> ideas and concepts to be fed into<br />

the process. However, such ideas should not be<br />

fully developed by project participants but could<br />

be communicated to the Board <strong>for</strong> further development<br />

in a top-down mode. The Methodologies<br />

Panel continues as the expert advisor of the<br />

Board.<br />

The described model will most likely increase<br />

costs at the Board level. On the other hand, it will<br />

be seen as desirable by project participants and<br />

will involve less cost at that level. Thus, it might<br />

be neutral in terms of transaction costs (efficiency)<br />

while at the same time increasing both input<br />

legitimacy and compliance certainty and quality<br />

(output legitimacy).<br />

The only option will be to abolish the<br />

present review procedure and let the DOEs’<br />

assessments be final, i.e. projects are<br />

registered and credits issued upon positive<br />

validation or verification by DOEs unless<br />

they are appealed against to the <strong>new</strong> body<br />

In the AWG KP, discussions are also being carried<br />

out into if and how objectives such as the<br />

promotion of sustainable development, the<br />

achievement of environmental and economic cobenefits<br />

and the transfer of technologies might<br />

be concretized by specific eligibility criteria.<br />

Implementing such concepts would necessitate<br />

the inclusion in methodologies of appropriate<br />

definitions and relevant criteria and indicators. A<br />

considerable ef<strong>for</strong>t would be needed to <strong>for</strong>mulate<br />

these requirements in a sufficiently standardized<br />

way in order to maintain clarity and efficiency.<br />

6.2. Setting standards <strong>for</strong> accreditation<br />

and validation/verification services<br />

The number of cases where projects or credits<br />

are not automatically registered or issued because<br />

a review has been triggered by three Board<br />

members has substantially increased since spring<br />

2007. The main reason is the availability in early<br />

2007 of adequate Secretariat resources to support<br />

decision-making by Board members and the<br />

quality management control system put in place<br />

by the EB. 15<br />

This development has revealed some discrepancies<br />

in the perceptions of quality requirements<br />

between the Board and the DOEs. Consequently,<br />

all categories of stakeholders have expressed<br />

concern about the legitimacy and efficiency of<br />

the system.<br />

Procedurally, the Board’s decisions to undertake<br />

a review take into account inputs from the secretariat,<br />

<strong>including</strong> the view from an outside expert<br />

(RIT). They also take into account comments that<br />

project developers and DOEs are invited to submit<br />

on the basis of requests <strong>for</strong> review. If a review<br />

is decided, its specific scope is determined, and<br />

project developers and DOEs have the right to<br />

submit their views once again.<br />

A final decision has to be taken at the second<br />

Board meeting after the requests have been<br />

made. This means that registration or issuance<br />

is not delayed by more than a couple of months.<br />

Nevertheless, responding to the questions raised<br />

and possibly undertaking corrections might involve<br />

additional un<strong>for</strong>eseen costs <strong>for</strong> DOEs and<br />

project developers.. In the view of the private sector,<br />

reviews are seen as setbacks <strong>for</strong> predictability<br />

and manageability. On the other hand, the Board<br />

is ultimately responsible <strong>for</strong> the quality of the<br />

15 2007 EB-report paragraph 91 (d).<br />

66<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


projects registered and, if in doubt, can only react<br />

by triggering a review. In order to ensure that<br />

review outcomes contribute to enhanced predictability<br />

over time, the CMP-3 has requested<br />

the Board to improve further the substantiation<br />

of its decisions in order to increase understanding<br />

of the underlying rationale by users. 16<br />

In the AWG KP the concern is raised about the<br />

DOEs assessing projects on behalf of the regulatory<br />

system while at the same being commercially<br />

connected to the project developers. The<br />

Board in its 2007 report to the CMP has already<br />

indicated, this situation might be perceived as<br />

potentially compromising. Consequently, a suggestion<br />

made within the AWG KP is to transfer<br />

the responsibility <strong>for</strong> selecting and paying the<br />

DOEs from project developers to the Board. This,<br />

of course, would need some procedural and management<br />

decisions.<br />

A more drastic suggestion is to abolish the whole<br />

accreditation system and let the secretariat per<strong>for</strong>m<br />

the work currently undertaken by the DOEs,<br />

provided <strong>new</strong>, appropriately trained staff and resources<br />

are made available and an appropriate<br />

fee structure put in place. Such a model would<br />

go against the overall trend. Other comparable<br />

verification systems typically operate with independent<br />

verifiers and through direct arrangements<br />

between the verified and the verifier.<br />

Consequently, instead of eliminating the DOEs<br />

from the institutional framework, the challenge<br />

is <strong>for</strong> the Board to continue to strengthen its ef<strong>for</strong>ts<br />

to establish a common understanding of<br />

methodologies and requirements and to synchronise<br />

quality perceptions. The means are further<br />

clarity of system requirements (cf. the above section<br />

on methodologies) and a further strength-<br />

ening of accreditation requirements, supervision<br />

and response when standards are not met. Such<br />

means are common in comparable systems, and<br />

they have been partly put in place already or are<br />

presently being discussed by the Board. They<br />

comprise:<br />

• The <strong>CDM</strong> Validation and Verification<br />

Manual (VVM) as a standard <strong>for</strong> DOE’s<br />

work, which the Bali CMP requested to<br />

be made the highest priority. 17 The Board<br />

has considered a draft at EB 41 and EB 42<br />

(September 2008) but due to time constraint<br />

could not finalize its consideration<br />

and will continue its discussion at EB 43<br />

in October. 18<br />

• Common and operational accreditation<br />

and re-accreditation standards, taking<br />

into account past per<strong>for</strong>mance. A draft<br />

document on accreditation standards is<br />

made available <strong>for</strong> public comments September/October<br />

2008 and will be considered<br />

by at EB 44 in November. 19<br />

• Spot checks triggered, e.g. after a complaint<br />

by a DOE, an NGO or a stakeholder<br />

affected or initiated by the Board itself.<br />

A number of spot checks have already<br />

been undertaken and have resulted in important<br />

corrective actions by the DOEs<br />

involved. So far no suspension has been<br />

decided.<br />

• Regular surveillance of, e.g., the management<br />

and organization of DOEs, and<br />

other mechanisms to ensure auditor and<br />

technical competences of DOEs. This<br />

could be elaboration of standard reactions<br />

or sanctions by the Board in cases of<br />

equally standardized per<strong>for</strong>mance imperfections,<br />

with suspension as the ultimate<br />

17 Do para.15 (b).<br />

18 EB 42 report, para. 9. http://cdm.unfccc.int/EB/042/eb42rep.pdf<br />

16 Decision 2/CMP.3 para. 15 (e).<br />

19 Do.para. 10<br />

Does the <strong>CDM</strong> need an institutional re<strong>for</strong>m?<br />

67<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


sanction. At the same time the Board aims<br />

at incentivising improved per<strong>for</strong>mance by<br />

rationalisation of the present system of<br />

witnessing, spot checks and surveillance<br />

activities 20 .<br />

• Regular dialogue between the DOE Forum<br />

and the Board, such as the dialogues on<br />

the development of the VVM and on accreditation<br />

standards.<br />

• Disclosure by DOEs of rejections, i.e.<br />

their decisions not to submit projects <strong>for</strong><br />

registration or not to request issuance. 21<br />

The result of such intensified ef<strong>for</strong>ts should result<br />

in validation reports and issuance requests<br />

by DOEs that correspond with the views of the<br />

Board. This would reduce the number of review<br />

cases, increase efficiency and make automatic<br />

registration and issuance the rule. At the same<br />

time, the issue of the contractual relationship<br />

would become less relevant.<br />

6.3. Re<strong>for</strong>ming procedures <strong>for</strong> final<br />

decisions on registration and issuance<br />

A CER as a commodity is fairly unique. Consequently<br />

the creation of such a commodity has<br />

to be based on innovative thinking. In terms of<br />

governance, however, the <strong>CDM</strong> is comparable<br />

with other regulatory systems. But unlike many<br />

of these, it is not a traditional command-andcontrol<br />

system and does not contain the traditional<br />

separation of functions. It monopolises<br />

in one and the same body –the Executive Board<br />

– regulatory, executive and quasi-judicial functions.<br />

Stakeholders have expressed a concern<br />

that this implies a lack of transparency, consistency<br />

and predictability, while at the same time it<br />

can be perceived as involving possible conflicts<br />

of interest. Regardless of the rights of project<br />

20 Do.para. 11 and 13<br />

21 See Dornau, Carbon Finance, April 2008, p. 18.<br />

participants to submit comments to review questions,<br />

it is felt that the present system does not<br />

sufficiently safeguard the legal position of the<br />

project developers, who expect that their voluntary<br />

participation should be met with the right<br />

to present their case under normal rules of law,<br />

i.e. input legitimacy. 22<br />

As ex-chairman of the Board, I can confirm that<br />

the Board deals with review cases extremely thoroughly<br />

and carefully. It is also worth noting that<br />

recent reports suggest that decision-making by<br />

the Executive Board has become stricter over<br />

time, referring to increased insurnce that reductions<br />

are real, measurable and not least additional.<br />

23 Furthermore, successful implementation of<br />

the suggestions offered in the previous sections<br />

is expected to reduce significantly the number of<br />

review cases, thus increasing efficiency. This does<br />

not, however, solve the basic question of a separation<br />

of functions. Consequently, consideration<br />

could be given to establishing provision <strong>for</strong> a<br />

second opinion on the final decisions on registration<br />

or issuance, which at present can only be<br />

reversed after resubmission of the entire case. So<br />

far, this issue is not among the suggestions being<br />

discussed by the AWG KP.<br />

Possible ption could be to set up an Ombudsman<br />

system or an arbitration or appeals procedure, as<br />

exists in comparable systems.<br />

Normally, an Ombudsman is an official appointed<br />

by the government or by parliament (in the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

context, it would be the CMP), who is charged<br />

with representing the interests of the public<br />

22 IETA’s 2007 report on the status of the <strong>CDM</strong>, different side events<br />

at COP 13/CMP3 on Bali, December 2007, Marcu at IETA side event on<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> at SBs, 11 June 2008.<br />

23 E.g. Flues, Michaelowa and Michaelowa: UN approval of greenhouse<br />

gas emission reduction projects in developing countries, University of<br />

Zürich, Center <strong>for</strong> Comparative and International Studies Working Paper<br />

no. 35/2008, . 2008.<br />

68<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


y investigating and addressing complaints reported<br />

by individual citizens. Introducing an<br />

Ombudsman has the disadvantage that his or<br />

her findings are typically non-binding recommendations.<br />

Consequently, the Executive Board<br />

could choose not to follow a recommendation<br />

to revisit its decisions. There<strong>for</strong>e, it is questionable<br />

whether such a model would increase the<br />

legitimacy of the <strong>CDM</strong> governance system. Also,<br />

introducing an independent appeals body with<br />

specific legal expertise and a <strong>for</strong>mal appeals procedure<br />

on top of the present system of review<br />

cases would be inefficient, adding an extra layer<br />

to the institutional system and definitely increasing<br />

transaction costs. In itself this might render<br />

participation in the <strong>CDM</strong> less attractive, in spite<br />

of the increase of input legitimacy.<br />

A simpler and more efficient model might be an<br />

appeals procedure covering procedural matters<br />

only. Such an appeals procedure is embedded in<br />

the procedures <strong>for</strong> accreditation in cases where,<br />

on the basis of a spot check, the Accreditation<br />

Panel recommends that a DOE be suspended. 24<br />

However, that model would not be satisfactory<br />

<strong>for</strong> project developers who were contesting the<br />

substance of the Board’s decisions, i.e.it does<br />

not add sufficiently to input legitimacy.<br />

Alternatively, an arbitration procedure could be<br />

set up with representatives of the EB, the project<br />

developers and DOEs, and possibly some independent<br />

individuals with a legal background. In<br />

such a model, the Board representative would<br />

have to assess the justification of his or her own<br />

decision in the Board, and the project developers<br />

and DOEs would equally tend to defend their<br />

original positions. Consequently, this model does<br />

not seem to be adequate.<br />

24 Procedure <strong>for</strong> accrediting operational entities, version 8, annex II<br />

(http://cdm.unfccc.int/DOE/cdm_accr_01.pdf).<br />

The challenge is to divide the Board’s functions<br />

and to refer the final decisions on registration<br />

and issuance to a separate and independent appeals<br />

body with legal expertise without at the<br />

No institutional changes beyond setting up an<br />

appeal body are needed.<br />

same time reducing efficiency. The only option<br />

will be to abolish the present review procedure<br />

and let the DOEs’ assessments be final, i.e.<br />

projects are registered and credits issued upon<br />

positive validation or verification by DOEs unless<br />

they are appealed against to the <strong>new</strong> body.<br />

This fits in with the expectations of more uni<strong>for</strong>m<br />

perceptions of requirements between the<br />

Board and DOEs, as well as the expectation that<br />

final registration and issuance on the basis of the<br />

findings by the DOEs will be the rule (cf. the previous<br />

sections). Decisions which still might be<br />

contested are dealt with under normal rules of<br />

law by the appeals body, whose decisions will be<br />

final, substantiated and published.<br />

For the “<strong>new</strong>” Executive Board, this means that<br />

decisions to undertake reviews and subsequent<br />

decisions on the cases will be replaced by decisions<br />

whether or not to appeal against a DOE assessment.<br />

Otherwise the Board will continue to<br />

exercise its regulatory and executive functions. If<br />

the Board considers that rulings by the appeals<br />

body reveal the need to clarify or revise regulation<br />

e.g. on methodologies, it might do so with<br />

effect to future cases. Generally the Board will<br />

be able to devote more time and ef<strong>for</strong>t to these<br />

functions to interact on generic issues with the<br />

DOEs and with project developers on the basis<br />

of their respective positions and functions in the<br />

system.<br />

Does the <strong>CDM</strong> need an institutional re<strong>for</strong>m?<br />

69<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


For the project developers, this means that the<br />

demand to have a right of appeal against the decisions<br />

of the system to an independent body under<br />

rules of law will be met. The right of appeal<br />

would further be granted to another DOE, the<br />

DNA involved and UNFCCC-accredited observers<br />

with a particular interest in the case.<br />

Conclusion: the Executive<br />

Board as supervisor<br />

As a conclusion, the following elements might,<br />

considered as a package, be of inspiration in the<br />

further process of improving the governance of<br />

the existing project-based <strong>CDM</strong>:<br />

• Top-down standardization and development<br />

of methodology tools and standard<br />

setting <strong>for</strong> accreditation and DOE per<strong>for</strong>mance.<br />

• Final registration and issuance upon validation<br />

or verification by DOEs unless appealed<br />

against.<br />

• Appeals to be dealt with by a <strong>new</strong> independent<br />

appeal body, which will take the<br />

final decisions based on legal expertise<br />

concerning the con<strong>for</strong>mity of cases with<br />

existing Executive Board regulations. The<br />

review process to be abolished.<br />

• The “<strong>new</strong>” Executive Board to continue to<br />

exercise its regulatory and executive functions,<br />

with the exception of decisions on<br />

registration and issuance.<br />

•<br />

The above changes would allow the Board to<br />

focus on and strengthen its supervisory role as<br />

<strong>for</strong>eseen by the Kyoto Protocol itself. This would<br />

also match existing competence requirements,<br />

which in collective terms are insight in the areas<br />

of climate change, of policy and of different<br />

geographic conditions. No institutional changes<br />

beyond setting up an appeal body are needed.<br />

From an efficiency perspective, top down activities<br />

will increase costs at Board level while abolishing<br />

the review process will decrease costs. At<br />

the project-developer level, costs will decrease<br />

<strong>for</strong> their own activities, and <strong>new</strong> costs will arise<br />

only from the appeal system. At the same time,<br />

the appeal system will increase input legitimacy,<br />

which in itself might increase the acceptance of<br />

the mechanism and hence increase activity and.<br />

in the end, output legitimacy. Of course, the<br />

modalities and procedures <strong>for</strong> the appeals body<br />

have to be more closely considered.<br />

The only remaining issue is that of possible compensation<br />

<strong>for</strong> Board members and alternates<br />

corresponding to their work load. But this will<br />

automatically come up as soon as appeal body<br />

members claim compensation on their part.<br />

Hans Jürgen Stehr is the director of an independent<br />

commission on climate change policy established by the<br />

Danish Government to examine how Denmark can reduce<br />

and ultimately eliminate dependency on fossil fuels. He has<br />

served in the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board since it was established<br />

in Marrakech in 2001, <strong>including</strong> two terms as Chair.<br />

Contact: hjs.cdm@gmail.com<br />

70<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Does the <strong>CDM</strong> need an institutional re<strong>for</strong>m?<br />

71<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


72<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Benoît Leguet,<br />

Mission Climat of the Caisse des<br />

Dépôts 1<br />

Ghada Elabed,<br />

University of Cali<strong>for</strong>nia at Davis<br />

A re<strong>for</strong>med <strong>CDM</strong> to increase supply:<br />

Room <strong>for</strong> action<br />

Abstract<br />

3,700 <strong>CDM</strong> projects are in progress in developing<br />

countries estimated to reduce emissions by a<br />

potential 2.7 billion tons of CO 2<br />

until 2012.<br />

However, the success of the <strong>CDM</strong> has put the<br />

system under strain: the estimated supply by 2012<br />

could be as low as 1.8 billion tons of CO 2<br />

. To<br />

enhance the capacity of the mechanism to increase<br />

emissions reduction ef<strong>for</strong>ts in developing countries,<br />

in particular in the energy and agricultural<br />

sectors which will eventually play a large role<br />

in abatement, we recommend the development<br />

of simplified and objective additionality tests,<br />

top-down methodologies and the re<strong>for</strong>m of<br />

the validation and verification procedure.<br />

Introduction<br />

While the success of the Clean Development<br />

Mechanism (<strong>CDM</strong>) has been praised by many<br />

observers, the mechanism faces today a number of<br />

challenges: increasing delays, difficulty in finding<br />

auditors to certify projects, and a great number of<br />

uncertainties <strong>for</strong> project developers (Schneider<br />

2007, Sterk 2008, Wara & Victor 2008). These<br />

challenges are the price of success: 3,700 <strong>CDM</strong><br />

projects are in progress in developing nations.<br />

These projects could potentially abate emissions<br />

by 2.7 GteqCO2 by 2012. The number of <strong>CDM</strong><br />

projects is growing and is putting the mechanism<br />

to the test.<br />

Based on analysis of risks and delays in the<br />

CER generation process, we propose certain<br />

procedural modifications within the existing<br />

institutional and methodological frameworks to<br />

enable the <strong>CDM</strong> to realize the sizeable emission<br />

73<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


eductions necessary to combat climate change<br />

and to quench the thirst <strong>for</strong> Certified Emission<br />

Reduction (CER) credits stemming from the<br />

Annex B countries and the European Union<br />

Emission Trading Scheme (EU ETS).<br />

In the first section of the article, we examine the<br />

principal characteristics of the projects currently<br />

in the <strong>CDM</strong> pipeline. We then examine in detail<br />

the implications of delays and bottlenecks in the<br />

process of generating CERs. The pre-2012 supply<br />

we evaluate at 1.8 billion CERs compared to the<br />

2.7 billion tons of CO 2<br />

potentially abated by the<br />

mechanism by 2012. This assessment hints at<br />

various ways to re<strong>for</strong>m and improve the <strong>CDM</strong> from<br />

2013 onwards: standardized methods of proving<br />

additionality; top-down methodologies and a<br />

re<strong>for</strong>med validation and verification process.<br />

Ensuring the success of the <strong>CDM</strong> in the post-<br />

2012 world is not only about lowering the cost of<br />

compliance <strong>for</strong> Annex I countries and involving<br />

today’s non-Annex I countries. It is also about<br />

setting a standard <strong>for</strong> project-based mechanisms<br />

that could help build an ambitious international<br />

climate regime <strong>for</strong> tomorrow.<br />

Potential supply of<br />

CERs through 2012<br />

A large potential, few countries,<br />

few technologies<br />

According to the in<strong>for</strong>mation available in the<br />

UNEP-RISOE <strong>CDM</strong>/JI Pipeline, 1 over 1,100<br />

projects have already been registered by the<br />

United Nations that could yield 1.3 GtCO2 of<br />

abatement by 2012.<br />

1 Source: UNEP-RISOE <strong>CDM</strong>/JI Pipeline, August 2008 (unless specified).<br />

The data does not take into account <strong>new</strong> projects that will enter the<br />

pipeline between today and 2012.<br />

Abatement through the <strong>CDM</strong> is focused on a<br />

relatively small number of technologies, often<br />

involving non-CO 2<br />

greenhouse gases with potent<br />

global warming potentials and potentially low<br />

abatement costs. While more than a hundred<br />

methodologies have been approved by the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Executive Board (<strong>CDM</strong> EB), 10 methodologies<br />

alone are expected to generate 80% of the<br />

potential CERs be<strong>for</strong>e 2012. Incineration of<br />

HFCs and N 2<br />

O should yield more than a quarter<br />

of all emission reductions in the <strong>CDM</strong> by 2012;<br />

capture and destruction of methane should<br />

account <strong>for</strong> roughly a quarter of the abatement.<br />

Nevertheless, more diversified technologies to<br />

avoid emissions of CO 2<br />

are also present: re<strong>new</strong>able<br />

energy projects (one methodology covers at least<br />

eight sub-types of technologies) should account<br />

<strong>for</strong> one third, and energy efficiency <strong>for</strong> one tenth,<br />

of the emission reductions until 2012.<br />

By mid-2008, 70 countries had submitted at least<br />

one <strong>CDM</strong> project to the UNFCCC Secretariat.<br />

By 2012, roughly 80% of the potential CERs<br />

generated by projects currently in development<br />

should be generated in the Asia-Pacific region,<br />

and one fifth in Latin America. Around half of<br />

the abatement should take place in China, 15%<br />

in India and 7% in Brazil. Five countries alone<br />

– China, India, Brazil, South Korea and Mexico<br />

– should account <strong>for</strong> more than 80% of the<br />

abatement from <strong>CDM</strong> projects by 2012, which<br />

indicates that a limited number of countries will<br />

actually participate actively in the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

According to the World Bank, China was<br />

responsible <strong>for</strong> three fourths of all <strong>CDM</strong><br />

transactions in 2007. The success of <strong>CDM</strong> in<br />

China is largely due to the country’s size and<br />

attractiveness, and to the early start it took by<br />

developing, among others, several large projects<br />

based on incineration of industrial gases. On the<br />

opposite end of the spectrum lies Sub-Saharan<br />

74<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Africa, with only 2.7% of the potential credits<br />

until 2012. The bulk of the Sub-Saharan projects<br />

are hosted by only four countries: Nigeria, South<br />

Africa, Ivory Coast, and Kenya.<br />

The two faces of <strong>CDM</strong>: Large-scale<br />

and small-scale projects.2<br />

The previous paragraphs might lead the reader<br />

to conclude that the typical <strong>CDM</strong> project is a<br />

large-scale non-CO2 industrial gas destruction<br />

project in China. This conclusion is partially<br />

correct. Because large-scale projects involve<br />

low abatement costs and generate significant<br />

amounts of CERs, project developers are willing<br />

to spend money on the lengthy <strong>CDM</strong> process,<br />

which involves developing a methodology and<br />

Project Design Document (PDD), hiring auditors<br />

to validate the PDD, paying the registration<br />

fee, abating emissions, measuring emission<br />

2 This section is partially based on Joergen Fenhann’s (UNEP Risoe)<br />

article: Carbon Finance, 19 May 2008: « Why are there so many smallscale<br />

projects? »<br />

reductions, and again hiring auditors to verify<br />

the emission reductions. As a result, large-scale<br />

projects have historically been among the first<br />

projects to emerge.<br />

However, more than 1,600 small-scale projects –<br />

which generate less than 60 000 CERs per year<br />

– are also being developed (see Figure 1). These<br />

types of projects represent 45% of all projects<br />

under development and could yield 245 million<br />

CERs by 2012. Small-scale projects enjoy some<br />

flexibility in the registration process that reduce<br />

transaction costs: a simplified PDD development<br />

process, simplified modalities <strong>for</strong> monitoring<br />

emission reductions, a reduced registration fee,<br />

and bundling of similar projects to reduce the<br />

share of fixed costs.<br />

Fenhann (2008) points out two elements -<br />

among others - that could explain the popularity<br />

of small-scale projects. First, while large-scale<br />

methodologies must be proposed by project<br />

developers and approved by the <strong>CDM</strong> EB in a<br />

Figure 1 – Breakdown of large- and small-scale projects by type<br />

Source: UNEP RISOE <strong>CDM</strong>/JI Pipeline Analysis and Database, 1 August, 2008.<br />

Room <strong>for</strong> action<br />

75<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


ottom-up process, small-scale methodologies<br />

are approved in a top-down process. This triggered<br />

the emergence of small-scale projects in<br />

The number of <strong>CDM</strong> projects is growing<br />

and is putting the mechanism to the test.<br />

sectors <strong>for</strong> which small-scale methodologies<br />

- but no large-scale methodologies - had been<br />

approved. This was in particular the case <strong>for</strong><br />

the 594 hydroelectric projects and 414 biomass<br />

projects, which together could yield 161 million<br />

CERs by 2012.<br />

A second factor seems more decisive: the characteristics<br />

of the projects, and the political and<br />

technical environment in the host country. HFC,<br />

N 2<br />

O and landfill gas projects are by nature largescale.<br />

Some projects are also by nature smallscale,<br />

in particular in the re<strong>new</strong>able energy sector:<br />

wind, solar, hydro and biomass. In this context,<br />

the political and technical environment in the<br />

host country seems to play a major role. Of the<br />

158 small-scale wind projects being developed<br />

in the world, 138 are hosted by India; 309 of<br />

the 504 small-scale hydro projects are hosted<br />

by China; and of the 328 small-scale biomass<br />

projects, 201 are Indian, 42 Brazilian and 23<br />

Malaysian. Malaysia has also developed around<br />

30 projects <strong>for</strong> composting oil palm residues.<br />

These elements seem to indicate that political<br />

will – and a favourable regulatory, technical<br />

and economic environment – can lead to the<br />

emergence of clusters of small-scale projects<br />

that can be at least partly financed through the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

A closer look at the supply<br />

An assessment of the real supply by 2012<br />

Having a project registered and<br />

credits generated is risky<br />

The principle behind the <strong>CDM</strong> is in theory extremely<br />

simple: any project that can be implemented<br />

thanks to the emerging carbon price and which<br />

generates an effective reduction of GHG emission<br />

of one ton of CO 2<br />

may claim a CER. However, in<br />

practice it is un<strong>for</strong>tunately not that simple.<br />

For the UNFCCC, the life of a <strong>CDM</strong> project begins<br />

the day the Project Design Document (PDD)<br />

is submitted to the public <strong>for</strong> comment. The PDD<br />

must then be approved by the host country, validated<br />

by a Designated Operational Entity (DOE)<br />

and registered by the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board<br />

(<strong>CDM</strong> EB). Once the project has been registered,<br />

it is eligible to generate CERs. Abated emissions<br />

must be monitored and verified by a DOE<br />

throughout the lifetime of the project. Once the<br />

emission reductions are verified, the <strong>CDM</strong> EB issues<br />

the corresponding CERs.<br />

The discussion in previous sections assumed<br />

that all emission reductions set <strong>for</strong>th in PDDs<br />

will actually generate CERs. Un<strong>for</strong>tunately, this<br />

is not the case. Delays and bottlenecks in the<br />

process will trim the potential amount of CERs<br />

that will be available be<strong>for</strong>e 2012.<br />

From the public UNFCCC data, we could not<br />

find any evidence of a PDD submitted <strong>for</strong><br />

validation that was not approved by a host<br />

country. Along the registration process, it can<br />

thus be reasonably assumed that a host country<br />

will systematically approve all projects that have<br />

their PDD submitted to the UNFCCC: first, it is<br />

in the country’s interest to approve a project, as<br />

long as it complies with the national sustainable<br />

76<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


development strategy; second, since drafting a<br />

PDD is costly, it is likely that project developers<br />

engage in discussions with the host country’s<br />

designated national authority while drafting the<br />

PDD. However, there were delays in approving<br />

projects varying from one week (Qatar) to 17<br />

months (Uruguay).<br />

Figure 2 – From reducing emissions to generating CERs: associated<br />

risks and delays<br />

PDDs<br />

P ro je c ts a t v a lid a tio n fo r<br />

m o re th a n o n e y e a r<br />

P ro je c ts a t v a lid a tio n fo r<br />

All PDDs approved by the host country are not<br />

necessarily validated by the DOEs and approved<br />

by the <strong>CDM</strong> EB. Several projects have been<br />

rejected during this process. Even if a project<br />

is approved by the <strong>CDM</strong> EB, the potential to<br />

generate CERs mentioned in the PDD might not<br />

be achieved <strong>for</strong> technical reasons: <strong>for</strong> example,<br />

if the implementation of the project is delayed<br />

or if its operation is suboptimal. On the other<br />

hand, a project might generate more CERs than<br />

originally envisaged in the PDD.<br />

le s s th a n o n e y e a r<br />

V a lid a te d<br />

p ro je c ts<br />

(in c l.re je c te d<br />

a n d<br />

w ith d ra w n )<br />

b u t n o t y e t<br />

re g is te re d<br />

R e g is te re d<br />

p ro je c ts , n o<br />

C E R s is s u e d<br />

4<br />

3<br />

2<br />

All these risks make the CER generation process<br />

resemble a funnel. See Figure 2. A great number<br />

of PDDs go into the funnel, but a much smaller<br />

number actually generate CERs as an end product.<br />

Delays due to bottlenecks, present in each step of<br />

the registration and issuance processes, lengthen<br />

the funnel and reduce the supply of CERs that<br />

will be available be<strong>for</strong>e 2012.<br />

R e g is t e re d<br />

p ro je c ts ,<br />

C E R s is s u e d<br />

CERs<br />

5<br />

Methodology used to assess the supply 3<br />

To account <strong>for</strong> the risks faced by <strong>CDM</strong> projects<br />

and to estimate the real number of CERs that will<br />

be available, we evaluated the potential amount<br />

of CERs generated by a given project based on<br />

the data available in the PDD and in the UNEP/<br />

RISOE <strong>CDM</strong> Pipeline <strong>for</strong> each month in the<br />

period from January 1 st , 2000 to April 30 th , 2013 4<br />

and applied four corrective factors:<br />

3 For a full explanation of the methodology, see Elabed & Leguet<br />

(<strong>for</strong>thcoming).<br />

4 The date of April 30 th , 2013 was chosen as it corresponds to the end<br />

of the second commitment period of the EU ETS, today’s main source of<br />

demand <strong>for</strong> CERs.<br />

Source : Mission Climat of the Caisse des Dépôts, 2008.<br />

• A “pre-validation factor” which measures<br />

the probability <strong>for</strong> a project to be<br />

validated within a year. Historically, 85%<br />

of all validated projects were validated<br />

within a year, and projects that remained<br />

at the validation stage <strong>for</strong> over a year<br />

were unlikely to be ever validated.<br />

• A “validation factor” which measures the<br />

probability <strong>for</strong> a project that began the<br />

Room <strong>for</strong> action<br />

77<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


validation process less than a year be<strong>for</strong>e<br />

to be validated by the DOE.<br />

• A “registration factor” which measures<br />

the probability <strong>for</strong> a project that has been<br />

validated by a DOE to be registered by the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> EB.<br />

• A “generation factor” which measures<br />

the probability <strong>for</strong> a project using the<br />

registered by the <strong>CDM</strong> EB to generate<br />

the amount of CERs mentioned in the<br />

PDD.<br />

Three delays are also applied to the estimate,<br />

based on observed historical delays:<br />

• The delay from the day the PDD is<br />

submitted <strong>for</strong> comments and the request<br />

<strong>for</strong> registration;<br />

• The delay from registration request to<br />

registration;<br />

• The delay between the date of the<br />

marginal emission reduction that<br />

generated a CER and the issuance of the<br />

corresponding CER.<br />

Additionally, an estimate of the <strong>new</strong> projects<br />

entering the pipeline until 2012 is carried out<br />

by observing historical trends by country and by<br />

sector.<br />

The long and winding road to CERs<br />

Bottlenecks increase delays<br />

Some bottlenecks are apparent in the process.<br />

The first observed bottleneck is the delay in<br />

project approval by the host country. This delay<br />

seems to be increasing <strong>for</strong> several countries, in<br />

particular <strong>for</strong> China, as the number of projects<br />

applying <strong>for</strong> approval increases. The second<br />

bottleneck is the validation of the project by<br />

DOEs: the validation process takes anywhere<br />

between 58 and 520 days, depending on the<br />

country, with eight months on average. This<br />

may be explained by the fact that DOEs are<br />

understaffed. They are losing auditors to project<br />

developers and <strong>CDM</strong> boutiques and it takes time<br />

to train qualified auditors. The third bottleneck<br />

is the <strong>CDM</strong> EB: the <strong>CDM</strong> EB issued CERs <strong>for</strong> the<br />

first time in October 2005. In 34 months, only<br />

7% of the potential CERs up to 2012 have been<br />

issued. With less than five years to go, a potential<br />

2.5 billion CERs have yet to be issued and it is<br />

uncertain whether the <strong>CDM</strong> EB can cope with<br />

the associated extra workload. This may indeed<br />

prove not to be the case, as <strong>new</strong> projects keep<br />

entering the pipeline every month, at an average<br />

rate of 120 <strong>new</strong> projects per month. In 18<br />

months, the number of projects at the validation<br />

stage has multiplied by 2.5, and reached 2,255<br />

projects in June 2008. During the same period,<br />

only 700 projects were registered (see Figure 3).<br />

Not every ton will become a cer…<br />

Throughout the process of turning the potential<br />

abatement of one ton of CO 2<br />

into a CER, the<br />

first hurdle is the “pre-validation factor,” which<br />

estimates the time necessary <strong>for</strong> the host country<br />

to approve the project. Upon applying this<br />

factor, we find that 25% of the Chinese projects<br />

(400 projects) and 20% of the Indian projects<br />

(roughly 300 projects) currently in the pipeline<br />

might never yield CERs. The second hurdle to<br />

overcome is the “validation factor”. Only twothirds<br />

of the projects in development could be<br />

validated. The third hurdle is the “registration<br />

factor”. This factor measures the probability<br />

<strong>for</strong> a validated project to be directly registered,<br />

and seems to depend greatly on the sector or<br />

the methodology used. In particular, validated<br />

energy efficiency projects – about which the EB<br />

has expressed concern regarding additionality<br />

– account <strong>for</strong> more than half of the projects<br />

that are either rejected or reviewed by the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

EB. The last hurdle to overcome is the actual<br />

generation of CERs. An emissions abatement<br />

project may under- or over-per<strong>for</strong>m as compared<br />

to the provisions outlined in the PDD. While the<br />

78<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Figure 3 – Evolution of the <strong>CDM</strong> Pipeline (count: number of<br />

projects)<br />

the end of the second compliance period of the<br />

EU ETS, the primary source of demand <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong><br />

credits. This estimate does not fundamentally<br />

modify the balance of credits generated by<br />

country: China should still be the largest<br />

supplier of CERs, providing 50% of all CERs by<br />

April 2003; 75% of all CERs will be generated by<br />

only three countries (China, India, and Brazil),<br />

and 90% by only ten countries (see Figure 4)..<br />

Source: UNEP/RISOE <strong>CDM</strong> Pipeline, 1 August, 2008.<br />

average registered <strong>CDM</strong> project yields 94% of<br />

the emission reductions it intends to produce,<br />

this average hides differences among sectors.<br />

Industrial gas incineration projects achieve over<br />

100% of their intended abatement and energyrelated<br />

projects achieve between 60-80%, where<br />

as cement, steel, agriculture and transportation<br />

projects deliver only roughly 50% of the emission<br />

reductions planned in the PDD.<br />

Around 1 billion CERs could be generated by only<br />

three methodologies: AM1 (incineration of HFC),<br />

ACM2 (grid-connected electricity generation<br />

from re<strong>new</strong>able sources) and AM21 (incineration<br />

of N 2<br />

O); and 75% of the expected supply would<br />

come from only eleven methodologies. Energy<br />

projects such as re<strong>new</strong>able energies, fuel switch<br />

and energy efficiency on the production side<br />

should generate 45% of all CERs by 2012. On<br />

the whole, energy efficiency projects, either<br />

demand- or production-side, should represent<br />

12% of all CERs. Incineration of HFCs, N 2<br />

O and<br />

Figure 4 – Breakdown of estimated supply of <strong>CDM</strong> projects<br />

by country (Total: 1.8 billion CERs)<br />

Our assessment:<br />

1.8 billion CERs<br />

Data extracted from the UNEP/RISOE <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Pipeline indicates a potential supply of 2.7 billion<br />

CERs by 2012. However, our estimate, taking<br />

into account the abovementioned bottlenecks<br />

and factors, is that only 1.8 billion CERs will<br />

effectively be generated by April 2013, this being<br />

Source: Mission Climat of the Caisse des Dépôts, based on UNEP/RISOE<br />

Pipeline data, 1 August, 2008<br />

Room <strong>for</strong> action<br />

79<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


PFCs should yield roughly 40% of the CERs, while<br />

fugitive methane projects such as pipelines, coal<br />

mine methane and landfill gas should account<br />

<strong>for</strong> 10%.<br />

Recommendations<br />

<strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Our analysis suggests that while the current <strong>CDM</strong><br />

should result in significant emissions reductions<br />

of 1,8 Gt through April 2013, it will not realize its<br />

full potential of generating 2,7 Gt of reductions.<br />

The difficulties faced by the current mechanism<br />

should only marginally impact the development<br />

of non-CO 2<br />

industrial gas reduction projects.<br />

On the other hand, they place at great risk the<br />

growth in projects in other sectors, among others<br />

energy production and agriculture. Projects in<br />

these other sectors will eventually make up the<br />

bulk of <strong>CDM</strong> projects, as the potential <strong>for</strong> HFC<br />

and N 2<br />

O projects is dying out. If we seek to make<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> an instrument that can help achieve<br />

significant emissions reductions in developing<br />

countries and serve as a key building block <strong>for</strong><br />

the post-2012 international climate regime, we<br />

must improve its ability to per<strong>for</strong>m.<br />

Three main recommendations emerge from our<br />

observation of the bottlenecks, risks and delays<br />

observed during the <strong>CDM</strong> project approval<br />

and verification process that may be used to<br />

strengthen and enlarge the mechanism: (1) use<br />

simplified and objective additionality tests; (2)<br />

develop methodologies in a top-down process;<br />

and (3) improve the validation and verification<br />

process.<br />

A. Use simplified and objective<br />

additionality tests<br />

Doubts have been raised by some observers as to<br />

the questionable additionality of some projects<br />

and the need to tighten criteria <strong>for</strong> proving<br />

additionality (see <strong>for</strong> example Michaelowa<br />

and Purohit, 2007; Schneider, 2007; Wara and<br />

Victor, 2008). These studies have focused on<br />

possible “false positive” projects i.e. possibly<br />

non-additional projects that do get registered.<br />

Surprisingly little material can be found on “false<br />

negative” projects i.e. possibly additional projects<br />

that do not get registered. This may be because<br />

these false negative projects are by definition<br />

never developed. There is un<strong>for</strong>tunately an<br />

inherent in<strong>for</strong>mation asymmetry between the<br />

project developer and the DOEs, and ef<strong>for</strong>ts<br />

to tighten the criteria <strong>for</strong> proving additionality<br />

might actually have adverse effects, as they would<br />

increase costs, delays and risks, and possibly<br />

increase the number of false negatives.<br />

On the contrary, additionality tests should be<br />

simplified and based on objective criteria, such<br />

as a positive list of technologies or technology<br />

standards, technology penetration rate and<br />

sectoral benchmarks, rather than on the existing<br />

tools. This would make it easier <strong>for</strong> the DOEs to<br />

validate projects, and easier <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong> EB to<br />

assess the work of the DOEs. On the negative side,<br />

such lists, rates and benchmarks would require<br />

a significant amount of time to agree upon and<br />

could turn out to be very data-intensive. But in<br />

the longer term, the costs of the system would<br />

certainly decrease. At the same time, the number<br />

of false positives would, also, most likely increase.<br />

It should be borne in mind that two similar<br />

approaches can be used to decrease the amount<br />

of potentially non-additional CERs that enter the<br />

market. First, some approaches <strong>for</strong> discounting<br />

CERs generated by projects whose additionality is<br />

80<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


not certain have been proposed (see <strong>for</strong> example<br />

Lambert, 2007). Second, potential windfall<br />

profits can be taxed away, and the proceeds used<br />

to fund climate-friendly projects such as projects<br />

that reduce emissions or climate change-related<br />

research. This is what the Chinese government<br />

appears to be doing with the sustainability tax it<br />

set up, whose proceeds feed the Chinese <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Fund.<br />

Simplified and objective additionality tests<br />

would gradually shift the debate from a projectby-project<br />

assessment to the assessment of<br />

programs or even policies. The real long-term<br />

benefit of a re<strong>for</strong>med <strong>CDM</strong> should in essence be<br />

to provide incentives <strong>for</strong> low-carbon investment<br />

by favouring the development of national<br />

policies and regulations. As we mentioned<br />

previously, the success of small-scale projects<br />

despite supposedly higher relative transaction<br />

costs indicates that political will, associated with<br />

a favourable regulatory, technical and economic<br />

environment, can lead to the emergence of<br />

clusters of emission-reducing projects. This<br />

is a good omen <strong>for</strong> programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> and<br />

could also provide a testing ground <strong>for</strong> policybased<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> pilot projects based, <strong>for</strong> example, on<br />

biomass in India or small hydropower in China.<br />

Sterk, 2008). Top-down methodologies could<br />

prove especially efficient <strong>for</strong> technologies<br />

that have a low penetration rate, such as CCS<br />

or energy efficiency projects. The challenge<br />

would obviously lie in agreeing on thresholds<br />

<strong>for</strong> the technology penetration rates, sectoral<br />

benchmarks, etc.<br />

C. Improve the validation and<br />

verification process<br />

In the current <strong>CDM</strong>, the <strong>CDM</strong> EB is secondguessing<br />

the validation work carried out by<br />

the DOEs with the help of the experts of the<br />

Registration and Issuance Team. This process<br />

takes time and may partially explain the<br />

bottleneck observed in the registration process.<br />

Furthermore, review requests and rejections of<br />

validations based on the assessment of experts<br />

could undermine the process in the long run,<br />

since DOEs could then become very selective in<br />

Simplified and objective additionality tests<br />

would gradually shift the debate from<br />

a project-by-project assessment to the<br />

assessment of programs or even policies<br />

B. Develop methodologies<br />

through a top-down process<br />

Another re<strong>for</strong>m that might be considered –<br />

and is hinted at by the success of small-scale<br />

projects – is developing methodologies using a<br />

top-down rather than a bottom-up framework.<br />

These types of methodologies, developed <strong>for</strong><br />

a limited number of sectors, should include<br />

additionality tests based on objective criteria<br />

<strong>including</strong>, as previously mentioned, technology<br />

or technology standard, technology penetration<br />

rate and sectoral benchmarks (see <strong>for</strong> example<br />

the projects they choose to validate. This could in<br />

turn deter project developers in some sectors <strong>for</strong><br />

which the proof of additionality or other elements<br />

in the PDD are too subjective, in particular energy<br />

efficiency projects. The registration process<br />

pursued by the <strong>CDM</strong> EB should rather focus on<br />

ensuring that an adequate validation protocol<br />

has been followed. In this respect, the Validation<br />

and Verification Manual (VVM) currently being<br />

developed by the Board is a good starting point.<br />

Additionally, the experts of the Registration and<br />

Room <strong>for</strong> action<br />

81<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Issuance team could per<strong>for</strong>m their review be<strong>for</strong>e<br />

that of the DOEs, since they have the sectoral<br />

and technical expertise that DOEs lack in certain<br />

cases. Hence, they can provide technical input<br />

to the DOEs <strong>for</strong> use in the validation process,<br />

rather than following the work of the DOEs and<br />

possibly contradicting their validation work. If<br />

this option is pursued, it would be necessary to<br />

pay the experts either by the DOEs or by an ad<br />

hoc fund.<br />

Our three recommendations are to develop<br />

simplified and objective additionality tests,<br />

top-down methodologies and to re<strong>for</strong>m the<br />

validation and verification procedure.<br />

In a very similar way, the verification process<br />

could be improved. The <strong>CDM</strong> EB may focus on<br />

checking that an adequate verification protocol<br />

has been followed. The goal of verification should<br />

not be to check the occurrence of every emission<br />

reduction claimed but rather to make sure that<br />

the risk of overestimating emission reductions is<br />

properly managed. Two initiatives of the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

EB are promising in this respect and should be<br />

pursued: the previously mentioned Validation and<br />

Verification Manual and programmatic <strong>CDM</strong>, <strong>for</strong><br />

which random sampling of the individual <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Programme Activities is allowed <strong>for</strong> verification<br />

(UNFCCC, 2007). The voluntary market could<br />

also be a source of inspiration: the Voluntary<br />

Gold Standard has set up a system whereby a<br />

share of proceeds from every project goes to a<br />

fund managed by the Standard. The purpose of<br />

the fund is to pay the verifiers to randomly verify<br />

projects. Setting up a similar system <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

would, apart from reducing overall verification<br />

costs, address the concerns of some stakeholders<br />

that DOEs have a strong incentive to validate<br />

any project because they are paid by the project<br />

developer and not by an independent body<br />

managed by the UN. It would also help address<br />

the looming bottleneck at the verification stage<br />

due to the lack of trained auditors.<br />

In a nutshell, the <strong>CDM</strong> EB should rely more<br />

on the DOEs, which are supposed to work <strong>for</strong><br />

and not against the EB. Governments have<br />

long understood that verifying income tax<br />

declarations is costly, hence they have taken a<br />

risk-based approach to spot tax evasion by using<br />

random sampling in the verification process. If<br />

CO 2<br />

is to become the 21 st century’s currency, the<br />

same approach could be used to the benefit of<br />

the atmosphere.<br />

Outlooks<br />

In eight years, the <strong>CDM</strong> has achieved a<br />

considerable task. First, in environmental terms,<br />

it should reduce emissions until 2012 by roughly<br />

1.8 billion tons of CO 2<br />

. More importantly, it<br />

has become today’s standard <strong>for</strong> project-based<br />

mechanisms, which even critics of the mechanism<br />

admit (see <strong>for</strong> example Wara and Victor, 2008).<br />

However, the success of the <strong>CDM</strong> has put the<br />

system under strain. Multiple bottlenecks have<br />

appeared and must be remedied in order to<br />

enhance the <strong>CDM</strong>’s capacity to increase emissions<br />

reduction ef<strong>for</strong>ts in developing countries. Our<br />

three recommendations are to develop simplified<br />

and objective additionality tests, top-down<br />

methodologies and to re<strong>for</strong>m the validation and<br />

verification procedure. These recommendations<br />

seek to expand the scale of the <strong>CDM</strong> among others<br />

in the energy and agricultural sectors. Eventually<br />

these sectors will play a much larger abatement<br />

role than the “low hanging fruits” of non-CO 2<br />

industrial gas abatement, which contributed to<br />

the early development of the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

82<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


The road to Copenhagen and beyond is clear: the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> crediting process should be streamlined<br />

and the mechanism should be enlarged.<br />

Expectations are high: some of the legislative<br />

proposals discussed in the US Congress include<br />

provisions <strong>for</strong> using international offsets.<br />

Equally, the European Commission’s proposal<br />

<strong>for</strong> the post-2012 EU ETS – which is today<br />

by far the main source of demand <strong>for</strong> CERs -<br />

includes a provision <strong>for</strong> crediting projects that<br />

reduce emissions outside of the scheme. Such a<br />

provision could either supplement the <strong>CDM</strong> or<br />

replace it in case it fails to deliver. If the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

succeeds in remaining the prevailing standard, it<br />

could help link the EU ETS with emerging carbon<br />

trading schemes in other nations, <strong>including</strong> a<br />

future American ef<strong>for</strong>t. Food <strong>for</strong> thought and<br />

room <strong>for</strong> action!<br />

References<br />

Elabed G & Leguet B (<strong>for</strong>thcoming), “The Clean Development Mechanism:<br />

How many carbon credits by 2012?”, Climate report, Mission climat<br />

– Caisse des Dépôts.<br />

Fenhann J (2008), “Why are there so many small-scale projects?”, Carbon<br />

Finance, 19 May 2008.<br />

Michaelowa A & Purohit P (2007), “Additionality Determination of Indian<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> Projects: Can Indian <strong>CDM</strong> Project Developers Outwit the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Executive Board”.<br />

Schneider L (2007), “Is the <strong>CDM</strong> fulfilling its environmental and sustainable<br />

development objectives? An evaluation of the <strong>CDM</strong> and options <strong>for</strong><br />

improvement”, Öko-Institut, report <strong>for</strong> the WWF.<br />

Sterk W. (2008), “From Clean Development Mechanism to Sectoral Crediting<br />

Approaches – Way <strong>for</strong>ward or Wrong Turn?” JIKO Policy Paper.<br />

UNFCCC (2007), “Guidance on the registration of project activities<br />

under a programme of activities as a single <strong>CDM</strong> project activity”, Annex<br />

38 to the minutes of the 32 nd meeting of the <strong>CDM</strong> EB.<br />

Wara M. & Victor D. (2008), “A Realistic Policy on International Carbon<br />

Offsets”, PESD Working paper #74.<br />

Benoît Leguet is a Project Manager <strong>for</strong> Mission Climat, a<br />

research and analysis center on carbon economics at the<br />

Caisse des Dépôts in Paris, France. His research is currently<br />

focused on project-based mechanisms, investment in carbon<br />

assets, and carbon neutrality, and was a lead contributor to<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> and JI guides published by the French government.<br />

Contact: BENOIT.LEGUET@caissedesdepots.fr<br />

Ghada Elabed is a member of the Mission Climat team<br />

conducting research and analysis on project-based<br />

mechanisms linked to the Kyoto Protocol, mainly the Clean<br />

Development Mechanism. She is an agronomic engineer<br />

with a Masters degree in Environmental Economics.<br />

Contact: Ghada.Elabed@caissedesdepots.fr<br />

Room <strong>for</strong> action<br />

83<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


84<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


By Søren E. LütkenPh.D<br />

General Director of Caspervandertak<br />

Consulting Beijing<br />

<strong>CDM</strong><br />

Developing Country Financing <strong>for</strong><br />

Developed Country Commitments?<br />

How to deal with the challenges of the prevailing unilateral<br />

financing of <strong>CDM</strong> projects and the lack of technology transfers?<br />

Abstract:<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong> has so far almost exclusively thrived<br />

on local non-Annex-I financing and technology.<br />

To alter this situation, changes in the modalities<br />

<strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> are needed. Such changes must<br />

address those corporate interests that see<br />

emission reductions as an opportunity. These<br />

are not the emission constrained entities located<br />

in Annex-I countries. To improve the ability<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong> to respond to its original purpose<br />

three options are proposed: Deregulate <strong>CDM</strong><br />

to promote (<strong>for</strong>eign) investor confidence in<br />

the mechanism; introduce <strong>for</strong>eign (Annex-I)<br />

technology requirements in the <strong>CDM</strong> projects;<br />

and/or establish a sector-based governmentto-government<br />

model that includes technology<br />

development, transfer, and deployment agreements.<br />

Despite initial assurances to the contrary, 1 it<br />

is generally overlooked that <strong>CDM</strong> rests almost<br />

entirely on investors in developing countries<br />

being willing to put up the finance <strong>for</strong> projects,<br />

that through the generation of Certified Emission<br />

Reductions (CERs), help developed country<br />

emitters avoid having to make such investments.<br />

Instead, developed country emitters are being<br />

offered non-investment-based ‘commodity cre dits’<br />

(i.e. CERs) from projects that, from an investment<br />

perspective, are in many cases comparable to<br />

similar projects in an Annex-I context. For example,<br />

1 It is actually not possible to find specific references in the Protocol<br />

or the Accords regarding exactly who is supposed to fund which kind<br />

of project. The only evidence is records of positions prior to the actual<br />

establishment of the <strong>CDM</strong> in Kyoto, as well as interesting exchanges of<br />

questions and answers between the EU, the Umbrella Group and the EU<br />

Commission (see FCCC/CP/1998/MISC.7 at http://unfccc.int/resource/<br />

docs/cop4/misc07.htm) after COP3 clearly spelled out that the focus<br />

<strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> was to increase FDI <strong>for</strong> emissions-reduction projects (see also<br />

Lütken & Michaelowa (2008) pp. 9ff.).<br />

85<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


erecting a wind farm in China is not significantly<br />

cheaper than doing so in Spain. This was neither<br />

the intention nor the expectation regarding the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>. Rather, the <strong>CDM</strong> was supposed to generate<br />

additional investment flows from Annex-I countries<br />

with high abatement costs to non-Annex-I<br />

countries with inefficient power supplies,<br />

industrial production and other deficiencies,<br />

thus creating the potential <strong>for</strong> exploiting lower<br />

marginal abatement costs.<br />

Compared to the still absent <strong>for</strong>eign investor,<br />

the motivation <strong>for</strong> local investors to adopt<br />

non-domestic technologies on normal<br />

commercial terms is limited…..There<strong>for</strong>e,<br />

unsurprisingly, the <strong>CDM</strong> also has a hard<br />

time promoting any technology transfer.<br />

The effect of this is that the financial flows from<br />

Annex-I to non-Annex-I countries that were<br />

expected on the basis of calculating the so-called<br />

‘marginal abatement costs’ are considerably<br />

lower than originally anticipated. Compared to<br />

the still absent <strong>for</strong>eign investor, the motivation<br />

<strong>for</strong> local investors to adopt non-domestic technologies<br />

on normal commercial terms is limited,<br />

being expensive, unfamiliar or even unknown.<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, unsurprisingly, the <strong>CDM</strong> also has a<br />

hard time promoting any technology transfer.<br />

When we look at improving the reach, quality<br />

and sustainability of the <strong>CDM</strong> in a post-2012<br />

setting, we should first of all ask ourselves if we<br />

are happy with the situation as it stands. If not,<br />

what would be the most appropriate corrective<br />

action? This article assumes that, presented<br />

with the above facts, none of the parties at the<br />

negotiating table should be happy with the<br />

present situation. There<strong>for</strong>e, the article presents<br />

options <strong>for</strong> potentially significant changes to<br />

the regulations governing the <strong>CDM</strong>. As step one,<br />

it demonstrates that distinguishing between<br />

threat and opportunity as investment drivers<br />

has a high degree of explanatory effect <strong>for</strong> the<br />

actual records of the market, i.e. that financial<br />

unilateralism must be expected in a marketbased<br />

structure like <strong>CDM</strong> because it is designed<br />

to promote the pursuit of opportunity, whereas<br />

emission constraints are treated as a threat by<br />

the targeted Annex-I corporations.<br />

The article discusses briefly the implications of<br />

unilateral investment mainly <strong>for</strong> additionality<br />

determination be<strong>for</strong>e moving to a presentation<br />

of three options <strong>for</strong> countering the situation: one<br />

includes the option of abolishing the additionality<br />

test altogether; the second <strong>for</strong>malizes technology<br />

transfer as a requirement <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> registration;<br />

and the third introduces technology agreements<br />

as a basis <strong>for</strong> sectoral approaches.<br />

To avoid misunderstandings of the message<br />

in this article, please note that use of the term<br />

‘unilateral financing’ should not be confused<br />

with the normal understanding of unilateral<br />

projects, which only refer to the existence of an<br />

emissions reduction purchase agreement at the<br />

time of registration with the Executive Board.<br />

Unilateral financing refers to the financing of the<br />

underlying asset, which only rarely stems from<br />

Annex-I parties.<br />

Background<br />

There are no specific statistics on the involvement<br />

of bilateral investment in <strong>CDM</strong> projects, and<br />

there is no requirement <strong>for</strong> project hosts to<br />

indicate the specific financing model <strong>for</strong> the<br />

project in the PDDs. However, most PDDs reveal<br />

what kind of involvement there is by Annex-I<br />

86<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


parties. A survey of the first 628 registered <strong>CDM</strong><br />

projects indicates that projects are generally<br />

unilaterally financed. It also provides evidence of<br />

the kind of Annex-I country companies that do<br />

invest in <strong>CDM</strong> projects, and of the geographical<br />

distribution of bilateral investment activities,<br />

however small they may be.<br />

Of the 628 projects, 48 more or less explicitly<br />

seem to involve <strong>for</strong>eign investment capital (there<br />

is uncertainty attached to the figures because<br />

the investment models are not disclosed). The<br />

48 projects are distributed among 29 different<br />

investors. Among those that have invested<br />

more than once are Agritech, Union Fenosa,<br />

Ecosecurities, Lafarge, World Wide Recycling,<br />

Table 1. Capital flows <strong>for</strong> private infrastructure in developing countries, million US$<br />

Investment<br />

Year<br />

Latin America<br />

South East<br />

Asia<br />

South Asia<br />

Middle East &<br />

North Africa<br />

Sub-Sahara<br />

Africa<br />

Total<br />

Investment<br />

1990 440 44 0 0 40 524<br />

1991 0 379 614 n.a. 0 993<br />

1992 5,140 4,128 20 0 0 9,288<br />

1993 2,857 5,578 1,051 2,927 0 12,413<br />

1994 4,076 6,823 2,075 205 76 13,255<br />

1995 6,457 8,371 2,809 0 77 17,714<br />

1996 9,639 11,063 4,079 0 428 25,209<br />

1997 22,912 13,435 1,469 4,608 754 43,178<br />

1998 18,916 5,190 1,291 1,620 715 27,732<br />

1999 10,611 5,176 2,593 858 585 19,823<br />

2000 14,382 3,502 2,414 150 451 20,899<br />

2001 6,239 4,178 960 2,182 713 14,272<br />

2002 7,423 3,461 396 30 484 11,794<br />

2003 7,171 9,735 843 360 1,297 19,406<br />

2004 3,325 3,769 4,235 1,199 56 12,584<br />

2005 4,562 6,294 1,384 400 1,359 13,999<br />

2006 7,144 2,626 2,953 2,336 616 15,675<br />

Grand Total 131,294 93,753 29,185 16,875 7,649 278,756<br />

Source: Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory Facility (PPIAF), World Bank. The Private<br />

Participation in Infrastructure Database (Accessed November 2007).<br />

Developing Country Financing <strong>for</strong> Developed Country Commitments?<br />

87<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Gamesa, Econergy, Panasonic and Mitsubishi.<br />

Japanese investors seem to focus on Asia, while<br />

the rest have a significant majority of activities<br />

in Latin America: there are 19 projects in Asia, 4<br />

in Africa and 25 in Latin America. Most projects<br />

seem to be joint ventures, <strong>for</strong> which the capital<br />

distribution between the local company and the<br />

<strong>for</strong>eign investor remains undisclosed.<br />

The 48 projects correspond to 7–8% of the total<br />

portfolio or the normal approximately 10% share<br />

of FDI in the Gross Fixed Capital Formation<br />

(GFCF) of developing countries. Thus, there is<br />

no evidence that FDI has increased <strong>for</strong> projects<br />

related to <strong>CDM</strong> compared to normal investment<br />

flows. Another important observation is that most<br />

investors are technology providers in pursuit of<br />

opportunity. Those who are not are industrial<br />

corporations with existing operations in the<br />

host non-Annex-I country, i.e. they align the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> opportunity with their existing business<br />

strategies.<br />

There is obviously no trace of any<br />

significant <strong>for</strong>eign investment effect<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong> – at least not so far<br />

The evidence from this analysis is that more than<br />

90% of <strong>CDM</strong> projects are unilaterally financed,<br />

and only an insignificant share truly reflects<br />

the initial idea of Annex-I entities moving their<br />

investments to areas where the marginal cost<br />

of emissions reduction is lower than in their<br />

domestic markets. Further evidence of this is<br />

provided by looking at general investment flows<br />

<strong>for</strong> infrastructure investments in developing<br />

countries. The PPIAF (Private Participation in<br />

Infrastructure Advisory Facility) of the World<br />

Bank provides statistics <strong>for</strong> private participation<br />

in infrastructure in developing countries. This<br />

advisory facility was set up in response to the<br />

remarkable growth in FDI <strong>for</strong> infrastructure<br />

projects in developing countries during the<br />

1990s, but the trend suffered a serious setback in<br />

1998 due to the Asian financial crisis. Projects had<br />

started to emerge from practically zero in 1990<br />

as investment climates improved and financing<br />

techniques, <strong>including</strong> risk mitigation products,<br />

evolved to provide acceptable rates of return on<br />

the investments. The bubble burst, however, with<br />

the financial crisis, which revealed the fragility of<br />

the market and the incompleteness of regulatory<br />

mechanisms, procedures and traditions.<br />

This happened be<strong>for</strong>e Kyoto and – ironically –<br />

came to a halt just as the Kyoto Protocol came into<br />

being. According to the PPIAF programme, 2 private<br />

investment flows <strong>for</strong> energy projects (the most<br />

obvious area <strong>for</strong> emissions-reduction projects)<br />

in developing countries fell from approximately<br />

US$43 billion in 1997 to US$28 billion in<br />

1998. But the decline <strong>for</strong> the energy sector has<br />

continued ever since, while other infrastructure<br />

sectors (telecoms, water, and transport) have<br />

experienced more diverse fluctuations. The<br />

investment level <strong>for</strong> energy projects fell to US$19<br />

billion in 2003 and decreased further to US$15<br />

billion in 2006 or about a third of the level in<br />

1997. Further, Latin America is dominant in<br />

the statistics representing half or more of the<br />

investments, while investments in East and South<br />

Asia together dropped to only US$5 billion in<br />

2006, from US$15 billion in 1997.<br />

2 http://ppi.worldbank.org/explore/ppi_exploreRegion.<br />

aspx?regionID.1.<br />

88<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Investment motivation<br />

There is obviously no trace of any significant<br />

<strong>for</strong>eign investment effect of <strong>CDM</strong> – at least<br />

not so far. So why, despite the obvious lack of<br />

investment appetite <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> on the part of<br />

emission constrained Annex-I entities, is <strong>CDM</strong><br />

thriving more than ever?<br />

It all has to do with investment motivation. 3<br />

Corporate decisions related to emissions constraints<br />

take the <strong>for</strong>m of a response to a threat (as<br />

opposed to the pursuit of an opportunity). this<br />

may be compared with taxation: allocation of fewer<br />

allowances than needed to emitting industries<br />

constitutes a kind of tax.<br />

Addressing such corporate threats requires managerial<br />

decision-making. Here, differentiation may<br />

be made between:<br />

- In<strong>for</strong>med decisions<br />

- Unin<strong>for</strong>med decisions<br />

- In<strong>for</strong>med non-decisions<br />

- Unin<strong>for</strong>med non-decisions.<br />

The non-decisions are rarely efficient responses<br />

to threats, but they do apply to the (lack of)<br />

pursuit of opportunities, typically taking the<br />

<strong>for</strong>m of neglect. This should not be confused with<br />

addressing a potential threat through inaction. If<br />

a threat can be addressed through inaction, then<br />

inaction will be the actively decided strategy.<br />

Non-decisions are less fatal when linked to<br />

considering opportunities rather than addressing<br />

a threat. If a single corporation is observed in<br />

isolation, threats affect its existing core activities,<br />

whether it acts or not. Opportunities, on the<br />

other hand, only affect the strategic position of<br />

the corporation if they are exploited. There<strong>for</strong>e,<br />

threats need to be addressed more urgently than<br />

opportunities need exploiting.<br />

Investments in <strong>new</strong> markets, compared to existing<br />

ones, normally take the <strong>for</strong>m of longerterm<br />

strategic investments due to the additional<br />

costs involved and the relative detachment<br />

from the national market. This is particularly<br />

true <strong>for</strong> obvious <strong>CDM</strong> potentials in largescale<br />

investments in energy infrastructure<br />

with long construction periods, long life-times<br />

and long payback horizons. It is not likely that<br />

such investments will be intended originally as<br />

stand-alone activities: they are rather part of<br />

a long-term strategy building on an analysis of<br />

long-term expectations in a given market. To<br />

exemplify with an essential quotation from a<br />

European power corporation: ‘If we had a power<br />

plant in India, we might consider a wind turbine<br />

there. But never a landfill. And not without the<br />

power plant’. This quotation poses two serious<br />

challenges to the expected willingness to pursue<br />

low-cost emissions-reduction opportunities in<br />

non-Annex-I countries: 1) the response to the<br />

emissions constraint will be linked to markets<br />

already addressed by the constrained entity and<br />

2) the possible investment will be restricted to<br />

technologies with which the investor is familiar.<br />

This constitutes significant limitations on the<br />

scope of possible <strong>CDM</strong> investment <strong>for</strong> the<br />

emission constrained entities. The message here<br />

is that, unless <strong>CDM</strong> investments can be linked to<br />

strategies that have already been developed <strong>for</strong><br />

entering <strong>new</strong> markets, <strong>CDM</strong> in itself will not drive<br />

the investment. If, however, they can be aligned<br />

with already developed strategies, they will be<br />

taken on board as an additional consideration.<br />

3 The following is a brief description of decision processes, taken from<br />

work done by Butler et al. (1993) and further analysed in Lütken and<br />

Michaelowa (2008).<br />

But let us look at how such investment decisions<br />

are made.<br />

Developing Country Financing <strong>for</strong> Developed Country Commitments?<br />

89<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Responses to threats<br />

Decisions made in response to a threat are<br />

different in character when compared to decisions<br />

relating to opportunities. Decisions concerning<br />

threats are made under a certain strain, which<br />

is not necessarily the case <strong>for</strong> the exploration<br />

of possibilities – although, of course, there are<br />

windows of opportunity. Threats are problems that<br />

need solving; potential investments are options<br />

that may be exploited. An employee presenting an<br />

investment proposal will be evaluated differently<br />

depending on whether the proposal solves a<br />

problem or opens up an opportunity.<br />

The presentation of an investment option is<br />

typically ‘emergent’: 4 there may or may not be<br />

a deadline, but it is only presented if and when<br />

employees believe it to be sufficiently attractive<br />

<strong>for</strong> them to gamble on their status in the<br />

corporation. It is a bottom-up process. Moreover,<br />

because an option is not (necessarily) critical<br />

to the corporation, it may – depending on the<br />

corporate culture – be more or less acceptable to<br />

think ‘out of the box’, i.e. not necessarily complying<br />

completely with core business strategies.<br />

If, on the other hand, there is a threat that needs<br />

addressing, there is often a deadline. Management<br />

most often reacts to an event or development<br />

that is external to the corporation. The typical<br />

demand will be a cost-efficient solution, but also<br />

a solution that is easily implemented. Employees<br />

typically deliver their proposal responding to<br />

requests from management. Hence, the process<br />

is top-down and ‘deliberate’. A solution that<br />

is proposed but dismissed does not make the<br />

problem go away: there has to be asolution.<br />

4 In an empirical study conducted in the UK in 1988 by Marsh et al.,<br />

it was shown that ‘explicit strategic planning, even at a divisional level,<br />

[seems] to have only limited impact on the generation and approval of<br />

investment projects; it was more emergent than deliberate’ (Butler et al.<br />

(1993), p. 54). There seems to be no urgency involved. The corporation<br />

can af<strong>for</strong>d non-decisions.<br />

An alternative must be sought, which increases<br />

the strain on both the corporation and the<br />

employees. The stakes are higher, the margin <strong>for</strong><br />

error narrower.<br />

This renders strategic investment decisions in response<br />

to threats implausible in two dimensions:<br />

1. The employee does not present an option<br />

with a potential profit or return on investment.<br />

Instead he presents an already anticipated<br />

solution. The employee will be evaluated<br />

only on the quality of the proposal.<br />

This particularly includes ease of implementation.<br />

Presenting a proposal that is<br />

conceptually distant from core business is<br />

risky: partly because there is relatively more<br />

focus on the proposed solution; partly because<br />

the ease of implementation of a noncore<br />

business proposal is relatively lower;<br />

partly because it involves a status evaluation<br />

of the employee (and his lack of ability<br />

to present implementable solutions); and<br />

finally because a rejected proposal sends<br />

the employee back to the drawing board.<br />

2. Investment decisions are more often<br />

emergent and less often deliberate. Concluding<br />

in light of the above, this suggests<br />

that strategic investments as a response to<br />

threats are generally less likely compared<br />

to strategic investments in pursuit of opportunities.<br />

This establishes two filters in assessing the<br />

likelihood of <strong>CDM</strong> investments in emission<br />

constrained corporations:<br />

Filter 1: The emission restriction is treated as<br />

a threat, which leads to a top-down decisionmaking<br />

process. Investment options are not<br />

sought in the first place, and while the employees<br />

do not necessarily understand any specific<br />

90<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


limitations on the range of optional solutions,<br />

they are likely to define a set of delimiting criteria<br />

based on their understanding of management<br />

priorities. Employees are unlikely to come up<br />

with investment proposals at all if other options<br />

exist.<br />

Filter 2: If an investment materializes as evident in<br />

order to address the threat, the employees will at<br />

first be aware that this is unlikely to be endorsed<br />

by management. Still having to solve the problem,<br />

however, their risk averseness will lead them to<br />

propose solutions that can be implemented as<br />

easily as possible. This means that they will stay<br />

away from more controversial proposals and keep<br />

options within the existing strategic or even<br />

tactical reach of the corporation with a high<br />

probability of endorsement by management.<br />

In most cases, the <strong>CDM</strong> fails on both filters.<br />

Investments, whether <strong>CDM</strong> or not, are out of<br />

scope in the first place because making an<br />

investment in itself is a poor solution to a threat.<br />

And because <strong>CDM</strong> encompasses several sectors<br />

and fundamentally covers only countries that<br />

do not <strong>for</strong>m core business markets <strong>for</strong> most<br />

emissions-constrained entities, the core business<br />

criterion that the employees will most probably<br />

pursue to ensure ease of implementation is only<br />

rarely fulfilled. Furthermore, employees will have<br />

particular difficulties in presenting their case<br />

in the unlikely event that they should decide to<br />

pursue the non-core <strong>CDM</strong> investment option.<br />

They can hardly justify investing time and<br />

money in the collection of in<strong>for</strong>mation. At the<br />

same time, a strong and well-documented case<br />

is what they need to convince management. If<br />

they are not specifically asked to look into the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> investment option, they are unlikely even<br />

to consider it. This means that <strong>CDM</strong> investment<br />

is in conflict with the normal ways in which<br />

investment proposals emerge in corporations.<br />

Pursuit of opportunities<br />

It follows from the above that <strong>CDM</strong> investments<br />

have to result from the pursuit of opportunity,<br />

and apparently by corporations that do not<br />

regard the emissions constraint as a threat.<br />

An illustrative case of a pursuit of opportunity<br />

created by imposing regulation would be the<br />

development of the Danish wind-turbine industry<br />

during the 1980s. With politically <strong>for</strong>mulated<br />

targets <strong>for</strong> the adoption of re<strong>new</strong>able energy<br />

sources in the Danish energy supply system, a<br />

…the issue is how to address this<br />

unilateral investment drive and bring <strong>CDM</strong><br />

back to its original idea of promoting<br />

investment and technology transfer.<br />

market <strong>for</strong> re<strong>new</strong>able energy technology was<br />

born. Seriously affecting the profitability of the<br />

energy supply (wind energy at the time being<br />

appreciably uncompetitive even at increased<br />

oil prices) the power sector could have been<br />

expected to pursue the opportunity to start<br />

developing and constructing wind turbines. It did<br />

commission two turbines and initiated research<br />

and development activities primarily related<br />

to operation, integration and control. These,<br />

however, seem to have been activities initiated<br />

solely as responses to the threat constituted by<br />

the obligation to include larger shares of windbased<br />

power supply. The special competence<br />

developed by the Danish utilities <strong>for</strong> integrating<br />

high percentages of wind-generated electricity<br />

into electricity grids has not been exported at<br />

all to the growing number of countries that are<br />

presently embarking on significant expansions of<br />

wind energy.<br />

The business opportunity inherent in erecting<br />

wind turbines – namely the production and supply<br />

Developing Country Financing <strong>for</strong> Developed Country Commitments?<br />

91<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


of wind turbine technology – was exploited by<br />

others, not the power corporations. Instead, Vestas,<br />

which has a history of producing, among other<br />

things, coolers and cranes (an obvious foundation),<br />

started production in 1979. Since then it has<br />

developed into the largest global manufacturer of<br />

wind turbines, initially supported by conducive<br />

local market conditions, and gradually expanding<br />

into other markets where equally favourable<br />

market conditions had evolved.<br />

This example indicates that it is not the product<br />

but the process that defines the core competencies<br />

of a corporation. The power corporations did not<br />

solve the problem because their own processes<br />

do not support the development of <strong>new</strong> products,<br />

only the optimization of their own processes.<br />

This also indicates that opportunities that are<br />

explored as a response to a threat encompass<br />

only those options that mitigate the direct effect<br />

of the threat. Broader market opportunities are<br />

explored by others.<br />

For <strong>CDM</strong>, the opportunity rests first and <strong>for</strong>emost<br />

with the local, unilateral project developers. They<br />

do not fail on the filters because there is no threat<br />

demanding any particular response. They can<br />

af<strong>for</strong>d to wait or to do nothing at all. The important<br />

question, of course, is why they choose to invest. As<br />

the analysis of the first few hundred <strong>CDM</strong> projects<br />

illustrates, developing countries’ own project<br />

developers and power corporations support<br />

virtually all <strong>CDM</strong> projects with their own capital.<br />

At first sight they should be even more remotely<br />

interested in emissions reduction compared to<br />

their Annex-I counterparts. But it turns out that<br />

their investment appetite in wind energy, biomass<br />

projects, hydro projects and energy efficiency<br />

beats their emissions-constrained colleagues<br />

in Annex-I countries. They are obviously not<br />

responding to any threat because there isn’t any.<br />

They are pursuing opportunity.<br />

On the face of it, there should be nothing wrong<br />

with that. But <strong>for</strong> those projects that rely on<br />

two revenue streams, power and carbon, what is<br />

questionable is whether these massive unilateral<br />

investments are driven by <strong>CDM</strong> and the relatively<br />

limited revenues from CERs, or whether their<br />

pursuit of opportunity rests solely with the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

registration of projects they were planning in any<br />

case. There are obvious alternative reasons, most<br />

of which relate to domestic policies: <strong>for</strong> example,<br />

the Chinese targets <strong>for</strong> wind- and biomassbased<br />

power generation, as well as targets <strong>for</strong><br />

energy efficiency in the thousand most highly<br />

emitting corporations. This relates to the issue of<br />

additionality, which has been discussed extensively<br />

<strong>for</strong> years. While unilateral investments do not<br />

clearly discard the additionality of projects, they<br />

do not support it either. It is entirely possible to<br />

identify unilaterally financed <strong>CDM</strong> projects that<br />

are truly additional and which also include the<br />

purchase of <strong>for</strong>eign equipment., However, the<br />

problems the <strong>CDM</strong> community faces in finding<br />

sufficient evidence of early <strong>CDM</strong> consideration<br />

to ensure project registration – and the recent<br />

EB response 5 requiring notification to the<br />

national DNAs of project consideration –<br />

illustrate concerns that motivations are<br />

being tampered with.<br />

The present records in the market also compromise<br />

the initial intentions regarding technology<br />

transfer, as the majority of projects undertaken<br />

by local investors seem to employ local technology,<br />

thus bolstering the argument that these<br />

projects are building on traditional investment<br />

motivations and that <strong>CDM</strong> registration is regarded<br />

as an opportunity associated with the usual<br />

business.<br />

5 In accordance with the EB41 report Annex 46, the national DNA<br />

should be in<strong>for</strong>med of any <strong>CDM</strong> project within six months from the start<br />

date of the project. The announcement is valid from 2 August 2008.<br />

http://cdm.unfccc.int/EB/041/eb41_repan46.pdf<br />

92<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


It is left it to readers here to determine how best<br />

to interpret the additionality consequences of<br />

the prevailing unilateral financing. The present<br />

author believes that the additionality test, as<br />

presently administered by the EB, is not an efficient<br />

guardian of the environmental integrity<br />

of the Protocol. More importantly, however, the<br />

issue is how to address this unilateral investment<br />

drive and bring <strong>CDM</strong> back to its original idea of<br />

promoting investment and technology transfer.<br />

Other structures may be more suitable in ensuring<br />

the original aim of promoting technological<br />

and financial transfers from Annex-I to non-Annex-I<br />

countries.<br />

Solutions to the problem<br />

De-regulate <strong>CDM</strong><br />

There are several ways to approach this issue. The<br />

idealistic approach would be to attempt to divert<br />

Annex-I investment capital from its present use<br />

into <strong>CDM</strong> activities. It is clear from the above<br />

that the emissions-constrained entities will be<br />

the very last to move on such an agenda, standing<br />

last in the queue of investors that pursue opportunity.<br />

Clearly, <strong>CDM</strong> investment so far has not<br />

been regarded as an opportunity by many Annex-<br />

I investors. The reason is that <strong>CDM</strong> can never be<br />

seen in isolation. Traditional investment drivers<br />

are paramount, and the addition of the opportunity<br />

provided by carbon credits is regarded as<br />

secondary – or, more appropriately, is considered<br />

an extra risk to the extent that business models<br />

depend on it. If the fundamental investment<br />

drivers are not attractive, then even a significant<br />

prize linked to the carbon credits cannot bring<br />

investors on board. It cannot turn a bad risk into<br />

a good risk: the chances of winning do not increase<br />

with the size of the prize.<br />

It can also be argued that the more complicated<br />

and unpredictable the approval mechanisms <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>CDM</strong> become, due to a continuous flow of retroactive<br />

alterations of the rules, the more the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

decision parameters are – and should be – marginalized<br />

compared to the core investment. And<br />

if they were not, the market should marginalize<br />

itself as being too unpredictable and too politically<br />

motivated.<br />

Thus, to reintroduce the <strong>CDM</strong> as an opportunity<br />

in itself, the rules of the game must be significantly<br />

de-bureaucratized. Such a move would in<br />

particular mean abolishing the additionality test<br />

and common practice analyses. This may not have<br />

…loosening (or abolishing) the additionality<br />

criterion implies no risk of flooding the<br />

market with yet another wave of credits<br />

from the big developing countries.<br />

as drastic consequences as might be assumed.<br />

According to an assessment of the developing<br />

countries’ ability to generate CERs based on their<br />

domestic project financing capability, the annual<br />

generation capacity <strong>for</strong> energy, waste and HFC<br />

projects is about 250-300 million CERs annually<br />

(Lütken and Michaelowa (2008) pp. 119-23). This<br />

figure can be increased by a number of factors.<br />

In particular, the inclusion of energy efficiency<br />

projects will have a positive effect on this figure,<br />

and other, smaller sectors may add equally to<br />

generation capacity. In fact, however, this assessment<br />

indicates that the CER generation capacity<br />

of developing countries may well be close to exhaustion<br />

when compared to the September 2008<br />

UNEP/Risoe assessment of the total generation<br />

of CERs from presently known projects. Here the<br />

estimate is about 1500 million CERs up to and<br />

<strong>including</strong> 2012 (i.e. approximately 300 million<br />

CERs annually). So loosening (or abolishing) the<br />

Developing Country Financing <strong>for</strong> Developed Country Commitments?<br />

93<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


additionality criterion implies no risk of flooding<br />

the market with yet another wave of credits from<br />

the big developing countries. Recent records in<br />

the Chinese market seem to support this interpretation,<br />

as the number of projects requiring<br />

financing is drastically increasing.<br />

If developing countries are close to their CER<br />

generation capacity, a total de-bureaucratization<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong> will probably not produce a significantly<br />

increased number of locally financed projects.<br />

From the investment motivations outlined above,<br />

…to reintroduce the <strong>CDM</strong> as an opportunity<br />

in itself, the rules of the game must be<br />

significantly de-bureaucratized.<br />

it should be understood that local project developers<br />

should be the first to move in pursuit of<br />

opportunity. And opportunity to them, first of all,<br />

would represent the registration as <strong>CDM</strong> projects<br />

of those activities that were on their books already.<br />

In any case, domestic investors do not need<br />

as much incentive as their <strong>for</strong>eign counterparts,<br />

as they are already in the market. But eliminating<br />

risks in the <strong>CDM</strong> system may attract the <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

financing that is presently evading the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

The result of such a move may be the fostering<br />

of more projects with a more cutting-edge technology<br />

content. It would also help overcome the<br />

backlog of projects that are presently stranded<br />

in a clogged validation and registration system<br />

which causes project owners increased losses by<br />

the day and compliance buyers unnecessary uncertainty<br />

as to how many credits will they actually<br />

be able to realize through their Emission Reduction<br />

Purchase Agreements (ERPAs). The value<br />

of such a move in terms of smoothening system<br />

operation could even outgrow the value in terms<br />

of improved technology transfer through greater<br />

<strong>for</strong>eign investment.<br />

Technology requirements<br />

But there are other, more top-down ways of<br />

shifting the balance towards greater financial<br />

and technological transfers through <strong>CDM</strong>. The<br />

problem with all of them is that they will reduce<br />

the eligibility of locally initiated projects. If, <strong>for</strong><br />

example, indigenous technology is excluded from<br />

registration, it would logically improve the relative<br />

share of <strong>for</strong>eign investments in <strong>CDM</strong> not because<br />

of increased <strong>for</strong>eign investment, but because of<br />

lower registration of locally financed projects. This<br />

would also be a logical consequence if a global<br />

common-practice analysis was introduced. Most<br />

locally financed projects are common-practice<br />

or business-as-usual projects and only seldom<br />

incorporate unfamiliar technology. Requiring<br />

the employment of transferred technology<br />

would immediately render a significant number<br />

of projects ineligible. To the extent that local<br />

investors respond to such requirements, the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

would respond to its original aim of fostering<br />

technology transfers. But the immense controversy<br />

in excluding developing countries’ own technology<br />

from <strong>CDM</strong> cannot be overlooked. Why require<br />

<strong>for</strong>eign technology if the local technology is<br />

comparable with or even outper<strong>for</strong>ms the Annex-I<br />

technology? The answer to that question, of<br />

course, is that there is no need <strong>for</strong> technology<br />

transfer in such cases. If technology transfer<br />

rather than emissions reductions 6 should be the<br />

objective and driving <strong>for</strong>ce behind <strong>CDM</strong>, then<br />

there should be nothing wrong in this distinction<br />

between technologies, as the <strong>CDM</strong> in those areas<br />

is apparently not necessary.<br />

It is difficult to say to what level a technology<br />

requirement in the <strong>CDM</strong> would reduce CER<br />

supply. It might go as high as 70-80% if we look<br />

at the number of projects that are presently<br />

based on local technology. But some of the loss<br />

6 Because the emissions reduction motivation behind <strong>CDM</strong> is already weak.<br />

94<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


may be recovered through an increased interest<br />

by <strong>for</strong>eign investors in bringing in technology.<br />

Carbon prices would in all likelihood increase<br />

significantly with a reduced supply of CERs and<br />

thus improve the case <strong>for</strong> a number of high-tech<br />

technologies that cannot compete against local<br />

low-cost and lower efficiency technologies, where<br />

such options exist.<br />

If this requirement was combined with the<br />

above proposal <strong>for</strong> de-bureaucratization of the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>, there could be a significant drive <strong>for</strong><br />

pursuit of opportunity from Annex-I technology<br />

manufacturers <strong>for</strong> bringing in their technology<br />

in non-Annex-I countries. This, of course, would<br />

depend on the conditions that might be attached<br />

to the technology transfer, whether this would<br />

be on a single project basis, or have a more<br />

programme-like approach that could ensure<br />

some sort of actual transfer of technological<br />

competencies to the local setting rather than just<br />

general technology diffusion. Such conditions, of<br />

course, could also deter technology providers from<br />

supplying their technology if the requirements <strong>for</strong><br />

giving up licenses or other rights are too steep.<br />

Sector-based approaches with<br />

technology agreements<br />

A last option would be to accept that unilateral<br />

investment will remain the prime driver of <strong>CDM</strong><br />

until the limits of unilateral financing capacity<br />

are reached – which may well be at just about the<br />

present level. However, if more sectors are opened<br />

up <strong>for</strong> reduction activities such as international<br />

transportation, a larger share of the Gross<br />

Fixed Capital Formation would be activated <strong>for</strong><br />

emissions-reduction activities and thus increase<br />

supply options. It could be appropriate to structure<br />

such <strong>new</strong> sectors in a more sector-wide approach.<br />

Sector-benchmarking, however, may be difficult<br />

in many sectors due to uneven distribution of<br />

the sector activities. This would be the case <strong>for</strong><br />

some non-Annex-I countries, in particular China,<br />

labelled as the factory of the world with only a<br />

few comparable sectors elsewhere. The energy<br />

production sector, however, may on the face of it<br />

have better conditions <strong>for</strong> benchmarking among<br />

countries, as energy demand is uni<strong>for</strong>m, though<br />

at different levels and <strong>for</strong> different purposes<br />

among countries. A sector approach, or maybe<br />

a sub-sector approach, would not change the<br />

financing and technological structures per se,<br />

but it could promote possibilities <strong>for</strong> larger scale<br />

government intervention through bilateral or<br />

multilateral agreement. Another argument <strong>for</strong><br />

addressing the energy sector is its significance in<br />

terms of emissions, as well as the immense lockin<br />

issues that the energy sector represents. A<br />

decisive technology-transfer strategy could avert<br />

investments in outdated technology 7 and produce<br />

significant prevention of GHG emissions.<br />

Bilateral or multilateral intervention in energy<br />

sectors could materialize as technologytransfer<br />

agreements, i.e. supported investment<br />

programmes. They should depend on privatesector<br />

choices of technology, as the public sector<br />

has a bad track record in pinpointing the most<br />

prospective technologies <strong>for</strong> development. But<br />

the intervention should remain a governmentcontrolled<br />

and government-regulated rollout<br />

activity, with generation of CERs not <strong>for</strong><br />

the private market but <strong>for</strong> intergovernmental<br />

exchanges of credits between the recipient<br />

and the bilateral or multilateral technology<br />

transfer partner. In that manner, technological<br />

agreements and government support could be<br />

weighed against the value in emission credit<br />

terms, while not necessarily counting ton by<br />

ton. Such agreements would be evaluated by the<br />

Executive Board, or more appropriately by other<br />

7 The IEA assesses that developing countries will need US$5 trillion of<br />

investments in energy infrastructure up to 2030, according to the Energy<br />

Investment Outlook <strong>for</strong> 2003.<br />

Developing Country Financing <strong>for</strong> Developed Country Commitments?<br />

95<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


institutions that are better suited <strong>for</strong> dealing in<br />

intergovernmental affairs. The technology and<br />

financial transfers would be secured through<br />

international agreement. They would probably<br />

crowd out individual, stand-alone, private-sector<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> initiatives in the sector, though local<br />

private financing would still be involved in the<br />

activities included in such government-driven<br />

programmes. The private sector would still be<br />

responsible <strong>for</strong> the base financing corresponding<br />

to the business-as-usual scenario.<br />

In some sense, this might correspond to the Global<br />

Environmental Facility’s (GEFs) ‘incremental cost’<br />

approach, but the scope, level of financing and<br />

above all the break from single-project approaches<br />

distinguishes this idea from the GEF. For all means<br />

and purposes, it addresses both technology transfers<br />

and the present unilateral financing imbalance. It<br />

has the potential to produce significant amounts<br />

of additional emissions reduction that can benefit<br />

Annex-I national emissions accounts, which may<br />

or may not come out as more generous national<br />

allocation plans. In any case, the Annex-I private<br />

sector will be left with a smaller share of non-Annex-I<br />

Gross Fixed Capital Formation <strong>for</strong> the generation<br />

of CERs due to the reservation of a large share of<br />

it <strong>for</strong> government-to-government initiatives. This<br />

could promote a demand-driven shift towards more<br />

sustainability-focused projects, depending on how<br />

the bilateral agreements on the technology transfer<br />

<strong>for</strong> emissions reduction are translated into national<br />

allocation plans.<br />

Conclusion<br />

The options outlined above may not be particularly<br />

sophisticated, but they address the<br />

unilateral financing problem in different ways:<br />

1) a bottom-up approach to increase bilateral<br />

projects, <strong>including</strong> de-regulation of <strong>CDM</strong>; 2) a<br />

reduction in the eligibility of unilateral projects’<br />

through technology requirements; or 3) a topdown<br />

approach to <strong>for</strong>ce efficiency gains in a<br />

sector which is most relevant <strong>for</strong> the energy<br />

sector. Option one may marginally increase the<br />

supply of CERs. Options two and three would<br />

decisively reduce it.<br />

If the opportunity-driven unilateral financing of<br />

projects indicates a less convincing additionality<br />

argument, such a reduction would improve the<br />

environmental integrity of the mechanism.<br />

That would correspond to a devaluation of the<br />

CERs from <strong>CDM</strong> projects. Devaluating CERs<br />

by allowing e.g. only 70% crediting of CERs<br />

corresponding to a 30% compulsory retirement<br />

would, however, not bring in additional benefits<br />

in terms of technology transfer. Such devaluation<br />

might not help increase prices on carbon either.<br />

In fact, it might do just the opposite, as the<br />

crediting value of CERs would be devaluated<br />

so that it would take more CERs to produce<br />

the same level of compliance. If it is true that<br />

developing countries produce CERs close to the<br />

limit of their investment capacity, an increase in<br />

CER supply may be less likely, but the price effect<br />

may still be the same, i.e. negative. Compared to<br />

this scenario, some of the technology approaches<br />

may fare better.<br />

But how would the different approaches address<br />

the investment motivation among project promoters?<br />

The de-regulation will work as an encouragement<br />

<strong>for</strong> all market agents to pursue<br />

a mechanism that, through such a move, will<br />

increase its image as an opportunity. Obviously,<br />

abolishing the additionality test would immediately<br />

lead to accusations of a further<br />

reduction in the environmental integrity of<br />

the mechanism and the Protocol. The paradox<br />

is that, by creating such increased motivation<br />

<strong>for</strong> pursuit of opportunity, particularly <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>for</strong>eign investors, <strong>new</strong> projects may materialize,<br />

96<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Table 2. Different approaches to altering the <strong>CDM</strong> and their effects on CERs and investment flows<br />

model<br />

effect<br />

Technology transfer Sustainability CER supply<br />

Effect on relative bilateral<br />

investment<br />

De-regulate <strong>CDM</strong> Minor increase No effect Minor increase Minor improvement due to<br />

increased FDI<br />

Technology<br />

requirements Significant increase No effect Significant decrease<br />

Significant positive effect<br />

due to ineligibility of many<br />

common practice projects<br />

Sector-based<br />

approaches<br />

Significant increase<br />

No effect –<br />

possibly small<br />

positive derived<br />

effect<br />

Significant decrease,<br />

but significant<br />

increase in emissions<br />

reduction through<br />

government trades<br />

Significant positive effect<br />

due to requirements<br />

of bilaterally financed<br />

technology transfer<br />

i.e. projects that did not happen be<strong>for</strong>e and<br />

there<strong>for</strong>e can be said to be additional. Once<br />

non-Annex-I investors have exhausted their<br />

CER generation capacity in investment terms,<br />

the risk of registering more business–as-usual<br />

projects is insignificant. Hence, paradoxically,<br />

eliminating the additionality test could lead to<br />

more additional projects!<br />

If technology requirements are introduced, it<br />

will shift the picture significantly. Non-Annex-I<br />

investors can no longer restrict the pursuit of<br />

opportunity to the registration of a project activity<br />

that would have been undertaken in any case.<br />

Now, the requirements will also en<strong>for</strong>ce a change<br />

of technology, which may be regarded as a risk<br />

to the original venture. Assuming that corporate<br />

investment decisions are equally emergent in a<br />

developing country setting, it raises the stakes<br />

<strong>for</strong> employees to propose non-conventional<br />

investment ideas. If corporate investment<br />

decisions are less emergent and more deliberate<br />

in such settings, the employees’ responses<br />

to management in<strong>for</strong>mation requirements<br />

will resemble a threat, which eliminates nonconventional<br />

proposals like adopting expensive<br />

and unfamiliar technology. It will, however, also<br />

foster a <strong>new</strong> situation <strong>for</strong> technology suppliers in<br />

Annex-I countries in seeing improved conditions<br />

<strong>for</strong> placing their technology in non-Annex-I<br />

markets. A stronger drive would lead to more<br />

opportunity-driven ventures. Also, Annex-I<br />

developers may follow the trend in pursuit of<br />

opportunity based on what to them is familiar<br />

but high-end technology.<br />

Finally, in the sector-based approach the picture is<br />

more diverse. The opportunities here are defined<br />

Developing Country Financing <strong>for</strong> Developed Country Commitments?<br />

97<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


as top-down, though the technology choices will<br />

still be based on private sector input. The pursuit<br />

of opportunity is at first within the Annex-I<br />

corporations, i.e. the technology providers, not the<br />

emissions-constrained entities, but the pursuit<br />

is with technology ‘placement’, i.e. prioritization.<br />

The roll-out of the technology transfer is the real<br />

prize <strong>for</strong> the technology provider. Depending on<br />

the design of the model, the technology transfer<br />

provisions may equally be seen as an opportunity<br />

by the recipient. But the recipient need not<br />

be the project owner: it may be a technology<br />

recipient identified through more or less public<br />

intervention, or even be a public sector entity<br />

like a university or a research institution. Hence<br />

the structures of motivation become much<br />

more complex, though the overriding driver of<br />

motivation is top-down international agreement<br />

and non-Annex-I domestic regulation.<br />

outside existing scopes and strategies. There<strong>for</strong>e,<br />

future regulation should more precisely address<br />

those entities, Annex-I and/or non-Annex-i, that<br />

see emissions reduction as an opportunity.<br />

Søren Lütken is the General Director of Caspervandertak Consulting<br />

Beijing, specializing in <strong>CDM</strong> and climate change consulting. He<br />

previously worked <strong>for</strong> the Danish Ministry of Foreign Affairs’<br />

Trade and was a Development Counsellor in re<strong>new</strong>able energy,<br />

climate change and the <strong>CDM</strong> at the Danish Embassy in Beijing.<br />

Contact: lytken@webspeed.dk<br />

The main message is that overcoming the<br />

predominant unilateral investment characteristics<br />

of the <strong>CDM</strong> requires initiatives that improve the<br />

motivation <strong>for</strong> pursuit of opportunity among the<br />

Annex-I technology providers and developers. As<br />

it is not realistic to improve the overall investment<br />

climate in non-Annex-I countries, initiatives must<br />

focus on regulation within the climate regime to<br />

change investment drivers. Such <strong>new</strong> regulation<br />

must represent options <strong>for</strong> pursuit of opportunity<br />

in a <strong>for</strong>m that is recognized and accepted by<br />

the industry and other market agents, who are<br />

supposed to increase their attention towards<br />

a <strong>CDM</strong> with more obvious promotional and<br />

regulatory characteristics <strong>for</strong> the transfer of<br />

technology.<br />

It should be recognized above all, however, that<br />

the regulated entities in Annex-I countries are<br />

not the target <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong>, as they will only react<br />

to the threat of regulation, and a threat does<br />

not entail responses in the <strong>for</strong>m of investments<br />

98<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


References<br />

FCCC/CP/1998/MISC.7 at http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/cop4/<br />

misc07.htm)<br />

http://cdm.unfccc.int/EB/041/eb41_repan46.pdf<br />

Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory Facility (PPIAF), World Bank. The<br />

Private<br />

Participation in Infrastructure Database (Accessed November 2007).<br />

http://ppi.worldbank.org/explore/ppi_exploreRegion.aspx?regionID.1.<br />

Butler, Richard et al. (1993): Strategic investment decisions, Routledge<br />

ISBN 0-415-07507-6Hb.<br />

Lütken and Michaelowa (2008): Corporate Strategies and the Clean<br />

Development Mechanism: developing country financing <strong>for</strong> developed<br />

country commitments. Edward Elgar 2008.<br />

IEA (2003): World Energy Investment Outlook 2003, Chapter 7. International<br />

Energy Agency.<br />

Developing Country Financing <strong>for</strong> Developed Country Commitments?<br />

99<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


100<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


DUAN Maosheng<br />

Tsinghua University, China<br />

The Clean Development Mechanism:<br />

Assessment of Experience and<br />

Expectations <strong>for</strong> the Future<br />

Abstract:<br />

With the aim of promoting further the <strong>CDM</strong>’s<br />

objectives, now is the time to look back and<br />

review the per<strong>for</strong>mance of the international rules<br />

and to consider possible improvements to the<br />

mechanism <strong>for</strong> the period after 2012. To this end,<br />

the paper provides an overview of the requirements<br />

<strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> projects by the Kyoto Protocol and<br />

the Marrakesh Accords. It then assesses the<br />

per<strong>for</strong>mance of <strong>CDM</strong> projects based on current<br />

practice regarding six aspects: emission reductions,<br />

sustainable development, environmental impact,<br />

technology transfer, geographical distribution<br />

and transparency, efficiency, and the effectiveness<br />

of the system in operation. Expectations <strong>for</strong> the<br />

post-2012 <strong>CDM</strong> regime are proposed. Finally,<br />

proposals on the scaling-up of the <strong>CDM</strong> are<br />

discussed and some initial thoughts considered.<br />

Seven years have passed since Marrakesh, where<br />

the basic framework of the international <strong>CDM</strong><br />

regime was established and the first commitment<br />

period begun. After the registration of the firstever<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project on 18 November 2004, the<br />

market has witnessed both a rapid boom in <strong>CDM</strong><br />

project registration in 2006 and flat or even<br />

stagnant development since 2007. To date, more<br />

than 1100 projects have already been registered<br />

with expected annual emission reductions of<br />

more than 220 million tCO2e, and a review has<br />

been requested <strong>for</strong> about 400 projects, a rather<br />

significant share. All major procedures within<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> regime have been well tested and<br />

significant experience gained.<br />

At its first session, the COP/MOP initiated a<br />

process to consider further commitments <strong>for</strong><br />

Annex I Parties <strong>for</strong> the period beyond 2012 in<br />

the <strong>for</strong>m of an open-ended adhoc working group.<br />

101<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Acknowledging the great contribution of the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> in mitigating emissions and promoting<br />

sustainable development in developing countries,<br />

and bearing in mind also various criticisms of the<br />

mechanism, at its fifth session the working group<br />

agreed that emissions trading and the projectbased<br />

mechanisms under the Kyoto Protocol<br />

should continue to be available to Annex I Parties<br />

as means to meet their emission reduction targets<br />

and could be appropriately improved.<br />

Now is the time <strong>for</strong> the international community<br />

to look back and review the per<strong>for</strong>mance of the<br />

international rules in promoting the <strong>CDM</strong>’s<br />

goals and consider possible improvements to the<br />

mechanism <strong>for</strong> the period after 2012.<br />

To this end, the paper first provides an overview<br />

of the requirements <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> projects. It then<br />

assesses the per<strong>for</strong>mance of the <strong>CDM</strong> projects<br />

in the context of these requirements, <strong>including</strong><br />

both achievements and challenges, based on upto-date<br />

international practice. Expectations <strong>for</strong><br />

the <strong>new</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> regime after 2012 are proposed.<br />

Finally, proposals on the scaling-up of the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> are discussed and some initial thoughts<br />

considered.<br />

Requirements <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> Projects<br />

Under the Kyoto Protocol, the <strong>CDM</strong> was<br />

established <strong>for</strong> two purposes: to assist non-Annex<br />

I Parties in achieving sustainable development,<br />

as well as contributing to GHG mitigation, and<br />

to assist Annex I Parties in achieving compliance<br />

with their quantified emission limitation and<br />

reduction commitments. It is also required<br />

that each <strong>CDM</strong> project should result in real,<br />

measurable and long-term emission reductions,<br />

additional to any that would occur in the absence<br />

of the project.<br />

• Under the Marrakesh Accords, some of these<br />

requirements were elaborated further:<br />

• a <strong>CDM</strong> project is additional if GHG emissions<br />

are reduced below those that would have<br />

occurred in the absence of the project;<br />

• it is the host Party’s prerogative to confirm<br />

whether a <strong>CDM</strong> project assists in achieving<br />

sustainable development;<br />

• project participants need to assess the<br />

environmental impact of the underlying<br />

project and, if those impacts are significant,<br />

an environmental impact assessment should<br />

be conducted in accordance with procedures,<br />

as required by the host Party;<br />

• <strong>CDM</strong> projects should lead to the transfer of<br />

environmentally safe and sound technology<br />

and know-how;<br />

• there is a need to promote equitable geographical<br />

distribution of clean development<br />

mechanism project activities at the regional<br />

and sub-regional levels.<br />

Furthermore, <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong> to make a significant<br />

contribution in these respects, the whole <strong>CDM</strong><br />

system should operate in a transparent, equitable,<br />

efficient and effective manner.<br />

The per<strong>for</strong>mance of the international <strong>CDM</strong><br />

regime is assessed, there<strong>for</strong>e, in accordance with<br />

the following aspects:<br />

1) Expected additional emission reductions;<br />

2) Contribution to the sustainable development<br />

in the host country;<br />

3) Environmental impact;<br />

4) Contribution to technology transfer;<br />

5) Equitable geographical distribution;<br />

6) Transparent, equitable, efficient and effective<br />

operation of the <strong>CDM</strong> system.<br />

Assessments of the Current <strong>CDM</strong> Regime<br />

1) Expected additional emission reductions<br />

Up to now, the expected annual emission<br />

reductions of more than 1100 <strong>CDM</strong> projects<br />

102<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


that have already been registered have exceeded<br />

220 million CO2e, a little more than the annual<br />

emissions of the Netherlands. Projects currently<br />

in the pipeline have almost the same emission<br />

reduction potential. It could be seen that <strong>CDM</strong><br />

has been a great success in terms of promoting<br />

the mitigation ef<strong>for</strong>ts in developing countries<br />

and in reducing the cost to developed countries<br />

of complying with their emission reduction<br />

targets under the Protocol.<br />

There is, however, also much criticism about the<br />

additionality of some types of registered projects.<br />

Since the final decisions on the registration of<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> projects and issuance of CERs are made by<br />

the EB (and not by a technical committee such as<br />

the Registration and Issuance Team), questions<br />

have been raised as to whether EB members,<br />

who are usually from government agencies,<br />

have the necessary expertise to make the right<br />

decisions. There are even suspicions that key<br />

decisions are being made on a political basis.<br />

The current additionality assessment requires<br />

that the specific situations of each proposed<br />

project should be verified and assessed, while<br />

the baseline scenario identification requires<br />

the determination of a hypothetical scenario.<br />

Both of these are processes involving subjective<br />

judgment and are by no means easy, although<br />

relevant evidence and the underlying logic<br />

involved should be presented and validated. EB<br />

members may be inclined to make a judgment<br />

based on their impressions of and preferences <strong>for</strong><br />

the particular technologies a project proposes to<br />

use, rather than on the evidence.<br />

Furthermore, since requests <strong>for</strong> a review have<br />

been made <strong>for</strong> an increasing proportion of the<br />

projects proposed, the uncertainties regarding<br />

registration and issuance have grown from the<br />

project proponents’ viewpoint. As a result, it<br />

is not easy <strong>for</strong> investors to take the incentives<br />

deriving from <strong>CDM</strong> into serious consideration<br />

when making their investment decisions. Some<br />

of them may prefer to make decisions without<br />

considering the <strong>CDM</strong> factor at all, while try to<br />

reap possible windfalls afterwards. The respective<br />

decisions of the EB and of investors will inevitably<br />

affect each other negatively, and both parties<br />

may find themselves confronted with a dilemma.<br />

…more and more investors, especially those in the<br />

re<strong>new</strong>able energy sector, are starting to take the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> factor seriously when making their decisions.<br />

2) Contribution to sustainable<br />

development in the host country<br />

In terms of numbers, more than half of the<br />

already registered <strong>CDM</strong> projects fall into the<br />

energy sector, with re<strong>new</strong>able energy projects<br />

accounting <strong>for</strong> the majority; about 20% are <strong>for</strong><br />

waste handling and disposal sector, while more<br />

than 10% deal with fugitive emissions from fuels<br />

and manufacturing industries. It is clear that<br />

most of the projects belong to sectors that have<br />

significant direct benefits in terms of sustainable<br />

development. In reality, more and more investors,<br />

especially those in the re<strong>new</strong>able energy sector,<br />

are starting to take the <strong>CDM</strong> factor seriously<br />

when making their decisions, and <strong>CDM</strong> is<br />

thus playing an effective role in promoting the<br />

development of relevant industries and thus<br />

low carbon and sustainable development in the<br />

developing countries.<br />

Some types of project, especially those dealing<br />

with GHGs from the chemical industries, have<br />

been heavily criticized by some because of the<br />

alleged lack of any contribution to sustainable<br />

development in the host country. Discussions<br />

Assessment of Experience and Expectations <strong>for</strong> the Future<br />

103<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


at the EB and the COP/MOP on relevant<br />

methodologies have also been at a stalemate<br />

<strong>for</strong> quite a long time. The difficulties of such<br />

discussions are still greater due to the potentially<br />

significant mitigation potential of relevant<br />

projects and their potential impact on the<br />

regional distribution of <strong>CDM</strong> projects. However,<br />

it is quite clear from the Marrakesh Accords<br />

that it is the host country government, not<br />

any other organization, who should determine<br />

whether or not a <strong>CDM</strong> project assists the host<br />

country in achieving sustainable development.<br />

Furthermore, there is no agreed definition of<br />

sustainable development. A mechanism could also<br />

be established to strengthen the contribution<br />

of such types of project to the sustainable<br />

development in the host country. For example,<br />

China has already established the China <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Fund, most of the income of which comes from<br />

the share of revenues from sales of CERs by <strong>CDM</strong><br />

projects dealing with end-of-pipe gases. The fund<br />

is being used to support activities dealing with<br />

climate change in the country. It can be seen<br />

that these types of project might also contribute<br />

significantly to sustainable development in the<br />

host country. Another important issue to be<br />

considered is that these types of project do not<br />

face the additionality challenge that many other<br />

types face and thus should not be excluded from<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

3) Environmental impact<br />

For countries without environmental impact<br />

assessment rules in place, the environmental<br />

impact assessment requirement will undoubtedly<br />

provide an incentive <strong>for</strong> the assessment. For<br />

countries with such rules in place, the requirement<br />

could promote the more effective implementation<br />

of these rules. In some of these countries,<br />

although the laws or regulations require relevant<br />

projects to undertake environmental impact<br />

assessments, these laws and regulations are<br />

poorly implemented in some sectors and regions,<br />

and many projects have started construction or<br />

even operation without such assessment being<br />

carried out or appropriate approval having been<br />

granted by the relevant authorities. To comply<br />

with the <strong>CDM</strong> requirement, project developers<br />

have to follow the host country requirements on<br />

environmental impact assessment.<br />

4) Contribution to technology transfer<br />

Technology transfer is not a mandatory<br />

requirement <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> projects. According to<br />

a paper prepared <strong>for</strong> the UNFCCC secretariat<br />

in 2007, roughly 39% of all <strong>CDM</strong> projects (both<br />

registered and proposed), accounting <strong>for</strong> 64% of<br />

the annual emission reductions, claim to involve<br />

technology transfer, which usually involves both<br />

knowledge and equipment. This is a quite high<br />

ratio, indicating that <strong>CDM</strong> has clearly promoted the<br />

transfer of technology to developing countries.<br />

It should be noted, however, that equipment<br />

imports account <strong>for</strong> most of the claimed transfers.<br />

Imports of equipment do not necessarily bring<br />

technology or know-how to the host countries,<br />

and most of them occur on a normal commercial<br />

basis. Without <strong>CDM</strong>, equipment imports and<br />

any associated transfers of know-how would also<br />

happen. The contribution of <strong>CDM</strong> to technology<br />

transfer, there<strong>for</strong>e, should be assessed on the<br />

basis of additionality, just like the emission<br />

reductions. Under this assumption, <strong>CDM</strong> has<br />

only promoted technology transfer in a very<br />

limited number of projects or types of project, <strong>for</strong><br />

most of which the major purpose is to mitigate<br />

GHG emissions, <strong>for</strong> example, projects using lowconcentration<br />

methane-oxidization technology.<br />

5) Equitable geographic distribution<br />

Currently, more than 60% of registered <strong>CDM</strong><br />

projects are hosted by countries in Asia and the<br />

Pacific, more than 30% in Latin America and<br />

104<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


the Caribbean, and less than 5% in Africa and<br />

other regions. Although some ef<strong>for</strong>ts, <strong>including</strong><br />

south-south assistance, have already been made<br />

to promote the regional balance of <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

distribution, much more still needs to be done.<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> is a market mechanism, and the private<br />

sector considers market potential and cost rather<br />

than regional balance when seeking potential<br />

projects. So developed country governments<br />

should shoulder the major responsibility <strong>for</strong><br />

promoting <strong>CDM</strong> projects in regions that are<br />

currently taking less advantage of the mechanism.<br />

It should be noted, however, that regional<br />

balance means promoting project development<br />

in regions such as Africa without limiting it in<br />

other regions.<br />

6) Transparent, equitable, efficient and<br />

effective operation of the <strong>CDM</strong> system<br />

Operation of the current <strong>CDM</strong> system, especially<br />

the per<strong>for</strong>mance of the DOE, the secretariat, the<br />

Meth Panel, the EB, etc., is currently faced with a<br />

great deal of criticism.<br />

Up to now, fewer than twenty organizations have<br />

obtained designation by the COP/MOP as DOEs.<br />

Given that about 2000 projects are still in the<br />

pipeline and more than 1100 projects have entered<br />

the stage of verification and certification, all the<br />

DOEs have actually been overburdened with the<br />

validation and certification work <strong>for</strong> quite a long<br />

time. This causes delays and sometimes a poor<br />

quality of work, and thus the loss of CERs <strong>for</strong> some<br />

projects with operation time be<strong>for</strong>e registration.<br />

For those DOEs with offices and local staff in the<br />

major developing countries, such delays to work<br />

are very serious. It often happens that projects<br />

cannot be submitted <strong>for</strong> registration be<strong>for</strong>e the<br />

deadline <strong>for</strong> old versions of methodologies, and<br />

thus the project proponents have to change the<br />

methodologies or versions of methodologies and<br />

go through the whole validation process again.<br />

The technical capacity of the DOEs is also causing<br />

concern <strong>for</strong> many. Although the accreditation<br />

procedure <strong>for</strong> a DOE is very strict and lengthy,<br />

many validators of DOEs, especially those in<br />

local offices in the host country, actually do<br />

not have adequate capacity <strong>for</strong> their work. The<br />

situation became even worse because of rapid<br />

turnover of experienced validators. Dealing with<br />

inexperienced validators is a genuine nightmare<br />

<strong>for</strong> project proponents. The absence of suitable<br />

internal training within the DOE is part of the<br />

problem.<br />

Imports of equipment do not necessarily bring<br />

technology or know-how to the host countries, and<br />

most of them occur on a normal commercial basis.<br />

Internal procedures of the DOE related to<br />

validation, verification and certification also<br />

need to be clearly laid down and presented<br />

transparently to project developers. In many<br />

cases, project proponents may find themselves<br />

lost in the DOE’s internal procedures, without<br />

knowing where their project has got to and<br />

who they should contact in case of need.<br />

Coordination between the DOE’s headquarters<br />

and its local offices should also be strengthened.<br />

In many cases, the headquarters and the local<br />

offices could both sign a contract with project<br />

owners in the same country, but project owners<br />

may find later on that their projects are being<br />

treated differently in the local offices and the<br />

headquarters.<br />

By its very nature, the DOE should behave<br />

neutrally and adhere to the rules laid down by the<br />

COP/MOP and the EB. It should neither establish<br />

<strong>new</strong> rules <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong> itself nor come up with <strong>new</strong><br />

ideas or create <strong>new</strong> requirements (<strong>for</strong> example,<br />

Assessment of Experience and Expectations <strong>for</strong> the Future<br />

105<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


key custom, or promise of project numbers) that<br />

may affect their neutral operation.<br />

The secretariat is mainly being criticized <strong>for</strong> its<br />

low level of efficiency. It very often happens that<br />

projects must wait about two months just <strong>for</strong><br />

completeness checks by the secretariat in the<br />

case of request <strong>for</strong> registration. This may mean a<br />

significant CER and income loss <strong>for</strong> the project<br />

proponents.<br />

In order to calculate precisely the emission<br />

reductions that have been achieved by a specific<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project, the Meth Panel and the EB have<br />

developed very complicated methodologies and<br />

tools. However, some of the requirements of many<br />

approved methodologies are either not very clear<br />

or not appropriate, and thus have created barriers<br />

to these methodologies being utilized. In the<br />

case of energy efficiency-related methodologies,<br />

<strong>for</strong> example, by 24 September 2008, no project<br />

had been published on the UNFCCC website <strong>for</strong><br />

global stakeholder consultation as part of the<br />

validation process <strong>for</strong> more than ten approved<br />

methodologies, a very significant proportion.<br />

This reflects clearly the difficulty of using some<br />

approved methodologies and the need <strong>for</strong> approval<br />

of the current methodology approval procedure.<br />

Furthermore, complicated methodological require<br />

ments also mean that project proponents<br />

should have strong technical capacity, which<br />

may impede the development of <strong>CDM</strong> projects in<br />

certain areas.<br />

With regard to the EB, besides other issues, the<br />

registration process is being criticized severely<br />

<strong>for</strong> its unpredictability and inconsistency. Some<br />

projects receive registration automatically, while<br />

other similar projects are reviewed <strong>for</strong> general<br />

issues which are equally relevant to the <strong>for</strong>mer.<br />

A more serious concern is that, in some cases,<br />

certain issues have already been discussed and<br />

settled by the EB during the process of project<br />

review, while requests <strong>for</strong> review are raised again<br />

<strong>for</strong> the same reasons.<br />

Another challenge facing the current <strong>CDM</strong> market<br />

is the uncertainties regarding market demand<br />

and price, especially whether or not the <strong>CDM</strong> will<br />

continue to exist after 2012. These uncertainties<br />

have already affected the continuation of ef<strong>for</strong>ts<br />

to develop <strong>CDM</strong> projects.<br />

Expectations <strong>for</strong> the Future<br />

A future <strong>CDM</strong> regime should address effectively<br />

the current challenges the mechanism is facing.<br />

First, the mechanism should be more efficient,<br />

equitable, transparent and simplified, should<br />

provide greater certainty to project investors, and<br />

should contribute more to technology transfer.<br />

The efficiency of the whole system, <strong>including</strong><br />

each major procedure, should be improved.<br />

Similar projects should be treated similarly, and<br />

balanced regional distributions of <strong>CDM</strong> projects<br />

should be promoted. Rules should be more<br />

transparent and clearer, leaving less room <strong>for</strong><br />

subjective judgment by relevant actors, and thus<br />

providing enough certainty to investors <strong>for</strong> them<br />

to consider <strong>CDM</strong> more seriously. Environmental<br />

integrity should in no case be sacrificed: on the<br />

contrary, it should be strengthened.<br />

Second, to create certainty <strong>for</strong> market demand<br />

and price, developed countries should not only<br />

commit themselves to deeper mitigation targets,<br />

but also <strong>for</strong>mulate and implement clear policies<br />

on the utilization of CERs.<br />

Third, <strong>CDM</strong> methodologies should be simplified<br />

significantly <strong>for</strong> the purpose of easy application,<br />

not focusing too much on precision, but<br />

providing better opportunities <strong>for</strong> conservative<br />

106<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


choices to be chosen by project participants.<br />

The project proponents should at least be given<br />

the flexibility to choose between complicated<br />

precision and conservative simplification.<br />

Fourth, it may be worth considering the possibility<br />

of modifying current institutional arrangements,<br />

<strong>for</strong> example, through a reallocation<br />

of responsibilities among different participants<br />

in the system. Given the workload and work<br />

quality of the DOEs, accreditation procedures<br />

should be simplified to increase the number<br />

of DOEs, while periodical assessment should<br />

also be carried out in order to make sure that<br />

DOEs have the necessary technical capacity and<br />

appropriate internal quality-control procedures.<br />

Another possibility is to establish more restricted<br />

but clearer responsibilities <strong>for</strong> DOEs and remove<br />

some of their current responsibilities to other<br />

organizations. For example, the role of host<br />

country governments could be strengthened<br />

on certain issues, <strong>including</strong> clarification of<br />

the mandatory legal requirements <strong>for</strong> certain<br />

types of project, dissemination rates <strong>for</strong> certain<br />

technologies, environmental impact assessment<br />

and stakeholder consultation requirements, etc.<br />

in the host country.<br />

Fifth, the EB should strengthen its executive<br />

role on the mechanism, mainly, <strong>for</strong> example,<br />

by providing the necessary and clear guidance<br />

to Parties, DOEs and project participants, as<br />

well as a systematic review of the issues that<br />

commonly arise in the project cycle, together<br />

with the necessary clarification and guidance.<br />

It should avoid becoming intensively involved<br />

in the discussion of specific projects, which<br />

should mainly be left to the relevant technical<br />

committees. To facilitate the work of the EB,<br />

its members should also possess the necessary<br />

expertise.<br />

Sixth, the role of external experts, especially<br />

industry experts, should be strengthened with a<br />

view to improving considerations of reality and<br />

reflecting it better.<br />

Seventh, a stronger, more professional, efficient<br />

and neutral secretariat should be established, its<br />

main focus being to support the EB.<br />

….some of the requirements of many approved<br />

methodologies are either not very clear or not<br />

appropriate, and thus have created barriers<br />

to these methodologies being utilized.<br />

Eighth, the additionality test could be removed<br />

<strong>for</strong> certain identified technologies, <strong>for</strong> example,<br />

wind power. This will provide the certainty that<br />

project investors require to make investment<br />

decisions and thus continuously promote the<br />

development of the relevant sectors. At the same<br />

time, environmental integrity could be achieved<br />

on a macro level through conservative baseline<br />

setting.<br />

The key aim of all future improvements should<br />

be to provide the necessary climate to promote<br />

the use of low carbon technologies through<br />

the mechanism, on the condition of assured<br />

environmental integrity.<br />

Scaling-up the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Scaling-up the <strong>CDM</strong> is now one of the focuses<br />

of discussion about the future <strong>CDM</strong> regime. It is<br />

advocated <strong>for</strong> various reasons, <strong>including</strong> ensuring<br />

the greater involvement of developing countries,<br />

addressing international competitiveness concerns<br />

and increasing the supply of low-cost<br />

Assessment of Experience and Expectations <strong>for</strong> the Future<br />

107<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


mitigation credits. The <strong>CDM</strong> was established<br />

<strong>for</strong> two reasons, namely to promote sustainable<br />

development in the host developing countries,<br />

and to assist developed countries to achieve<br />

their mitigation targets under the Kyoto<br />

…to create certainty <strong>for</strong> market demand<br />

and price, developed countries should not<br />

only commit themselves to deeper mitigation<br />

targets, but also <strong>for</strong>mulate and implement<br />

clear policies on the utilization of CERs.<br />

Protocol. It should not be expected to shoulder<br />

responsibilities other than these two, such<br />

as promoting the greater involvement of<br />

developing countries or addressing international<br />

competitiveness concerns. Other issues should<br />

be considered as part of other right <strong>for</strong>ums than<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

There are many proposals <strong>for</strong> the scaling-up of<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong>, many with different names, but they<br />

can basically be divided into four categories:<br />

absolute target-based crediting mechanism,<br />

intensity-based crediting mechanism, policy<br />

and measure-based crediting mechanism, and<br />

technology-based crediting mechanism. For all<br />

of them, the underlying logics are the same, i.e.<br />

first establish a baseline, and then compare the<br />

baseline with the actual per<strong>for</strong>mance of relevant<br />

sectors to determine whether or not emission<br />

reductions could be generated, and if so, the<br />

amount of emission reductions. Furthermore, in<br />

all cases the baseline and follow-up assessment<br />

approaches should be reviewed and approved<br />

through relevant international procedures; if<br />

the pre-established target is not achieved, no<br />

penalty will apply. The major difference between<br />

these approaches is the <strong>for</strong>mat of the baseline,<br />

i.e. absolute targets, intensity targets, policy<br />

and measures implementation or technology<br />

implementation.<br />

For an absolute target-based crediting mechanism,<br />

the political readiness of developing countries to<br />

accept it is the major challenge. Furthermore, the<br />

establishment of a reliable baseline depends on<br />

a precise projection of future emissions, that is,<br />

the product of the output and emissions intensity<br />

per unit product, of the associated sectors.<br />

Such projections, however, have been proved<br />

by history to be very difficult if not impossible<br />

tasks, especially <strong>for</strong> rapidly developing countries.<br />

This being the case, one possible solution is to<br />

establish a loose target that may be accepted<br />

by the host country, but the question is how to<br />

ensure that real additional emission reductions<br />

can be achieved.<br />

An intensity-based crediting mechanism is more<br />

acceptable to developing countries from the<br />

political point of view compared with the absolutetarget<br />

based approach. The technical difficulties,<br />

however, remain the same. For sectors with lots of<br />

heterogeneous products, it may be necessary to<br />

establish different baselines <strong>for</strong> different project<br />

types, which could be very time-consuming.<br />

Data availability is another key challenge <strong>for</strong><br />

this approach. For most developing countries,<br />

publicly available and reliable in<strong>for</strong>mation that<br />

is necessary <strong>for</strong> the establishment of the baseline<br />

is always a serious challenge. This is even true <strong>for</strong><br />

most large developing countries, which people<br />

think should have more complete statistical<br />

systems and stronger technical capacity. To<br />

ensure that credits will be issued <strong>for</strong> additional<br />

emission reductions remains another great<br />

challenge.<br />

108<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


A policy and measure-based crediting mechanism<br />

seems to be acceptable to developing countries<br />

politically. The major challenge is how to assess<br />

the emission reduction benefits of a specific<br />

policy or measure: emission reductions are the<br />

result of many integrated factors, and it is very<br />

difficult to separate out the effects and attribute<br />

them to different factors.<br />

transfer of technology to developing countries<br />

from developed countries more effectively. For<br />

example, one possibility is that the emission<br />

reductions associated with the application of<br />

eligible technologies transferred from developed<br />

countries will be allocated to the latter, while the<br />

receiving developing countries could benefit from<br />

the associated local sustainable development.<br />

There are different understandings of a<br />

technology-based crediting mechanism. One<br />

is that projects utilizing certain technologies<br />

are automatically considered eligible under<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> and thus could generate emission<br />

reduction credits, i.e. the additionality test is<br />

waived <strong>for</strong> such projects. The risks of free-riding<br />

and exaggeration of emission baselines and thus<br />

emission reductions could be eliminated through<br />

the careful selection of eligible technologies,<br />

the careful determination of relevant emission<br />

baselines, and the strong participation of host<br />

country governments and relevant national and<br />

international industry associations. Furthermore,<br />

be<strong>for</strong>e developing a project, the project<br />

developers could know in advance the eligibility<br />

of their projects under this mechanism and<br />

the rough amount of emission reductions their<br />

projects should achieve, which could encourage<br />

the realization of emission reduction potentials<br />

in relevant industries. Compared with the<br />

current <strong>CDM</strong>, more data are needed. However,<br />

through the participation of the host country<br />

governments and the industry associations, this<br />

may not be a huge challenge. Alternatively, only<br />

technologies <strong>for</strong> which relevant in<strong>for</strong>mation is<br />

available will be included in the eligible list. For<br />

project developers, the data requirement will be<br />

greatly reduced and will mainly concern general<br />

project-specific technical in<strong>for</strong>mation. Such data<br />

could be rather easily accessed and verified by<br />

the validators. Such an approach, given its direct<br />

association with technologies, could promote the<br />

Conclusions<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong> is serving its dual purposes well<br />

while also facing many challenges, <strong>including</strong><br />

increasing uncertainties regarding registration,<br />

its limited contribution to technology transfer,<br />

the uneven regional distribution of projects, and<br />

necessary improvements to the transparency,<br />

efficiency and effectiveness of the system in<br />

operation. The post-2012 <strong>CDM</strong> regime should<br />

try to address these challenges above all else.<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong> should adhere to the purposes <strong>for</strong><br />

which it was established, i.e. assisting developing<br />

countries in achieving sustainable development,<br />

and assisting the developed countries in<br />

achieving their mitigation targets under the<br />

Kyoto Protocol. Any future improvements to the<br />

rules should be directed to achieving these goals<br />

better. The mechanism should not be expected<br />

to shoulder other responsibilities not laid down<br />

by the Protocol.<br />

Duan Maosheng is a senior researcher with the Global Climate<br />

Change Institute of Tsinghua University. Since 2000, he has<br />

been involved in various aspects of the <strong>CDM</strong> from international<br />

negotiations to methodology and project development.<br />

Contact: duanmsh@mail.tsinghua.edu.cn<br />

Assessment of Experience and Expectations <strong>for</strong> the Future<br />

109<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


110<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Sergio Sanchez,<br />

Clean Air Institute<br />

Re<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>CDM</strong> and Scaling-Up<br />

Finance <strong>for</strong> Sustainable<br />

Urban Transport<br />

Abstract<br />

Improvement of urban transport systems in<br />

developing countries has an enormous potential<br />

to mitigate greenhouse gases while addressing<br />

other urgent environmental, social and economic<br />

issues. However, the transport sector is not<br />

well represented in the Clean Development<br />

Mechanism (<strong>CDM</strong>) portfolio. There appears to be<br />

opportunities to improve the <strong>CDM</strong> by broadening<br />

its scope and simplifying its rules. Furthermore,<br />

there is an urgent need to develop improved policy<br />

instruments to enable expanded international<br />

cooperation. A strategy to re<strong>for</strong>m the <strong>CDM</strong> and<br />

scaling up carbon finance to foster sustainable<br />

urban transport is outlined in this paper.<br />

Transport and climate change<br />

The Kyoto Protocol entered into <strong>for</strong>ce in 2005.<br />

A year earlier, global anthropogenic emissions<br />

amounted to 49 GTCO2-eq. These emissions<br />

were 25% higher than in the early nineties, when<br />

the United Nations Framework Convention on<br />

Climate Change (UNFCCC) was adopted. Global<br />

greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions could triple in<br />

2050 compared to the levels reached in 2004<br />

if no additional climate change policies are<br />

implemented (IPCC, 2007).<br />

The transport sector is one of the largest and<br />

fastest growing GHG sources. Between 1970 and<br />

2004, global GHG emissions from the transport<br />

sector increased by 120% globally, reaching<br />

6.4 GTCO2-eq (13.4% of the total). While<br />

industrialized countries still hold the largest<br />

share of GHG emissions from the transport sector,<br />

111<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


With the current climate change<br />

mitigation policies and related<br />

sustainable development practices,<br />

global GHG emissions will continue to<br />

grow over the next few decades.… Two<br />

thirds to three quarters of this increase<br />

in CO2 emissions is projected to come<br />

from non-Annex 1 countries.…”<br />

Intergovernmental Panel<br />

of Climate Change<br />

Intergovernmental Panel of Climate Change<br />

emissions from developing countries are growing<br />

rapidly. Between 1990 and 2002, transportrelated<br />

CO2 emissions doubled in China,<br />

Indonesia and South Korea. Looking ahead,<br />

the International Energy Agency (IEA) expects<br />

soaring increases in China (143%), Indonesia<br />

(122%), India (91%) and Mexico (71%) by 2020<br />

compared with current levels (IEA 2006).<br />

In addition, transport is the major source of<br />

urban air pollution. Air pollution in cities<br />

throughout developing countries affects the<br />

health and well-being of billions of people as<br />

well as the environment. Poor air quality results<br />

in hundreds of thousands of premature deaths<br />

and billions of dollars in medical costs and lost<br />

productivity each year (CAI 2007).<br />

Scientific knowledge, as well as current and<br />

projected levels of air pollution and emissions<br />

rates of greenhouse gases in urban areas of<br />

developing countries, confirms that there is a<br />

critical need <strong>for</strong> integrated, <strong>for</strong>ward-looking,<br />

comprehensive measures to improve air quality<br />

and minimize the risks associated with climate<br />

change at the local, national, regional, and<br />

international levels (GAP 2008, CAI 2007).<br />

As the impacts of air pollution and climate<br />

change on public health and the environment<br />

are better understood, the need to adopt<br />

strategies that recognize the importance of<br />

effectively integrating climate change and airquality<br />

considerations into social and economic<br />

development planning becomes more apparent.<br />

Burning fossil fuels is the most common source of<br />

both greenhouse gas and air pollution emissions.<br />

Furthermore, air pollutants like black carbon and<br />

tropospheric ozone, which are largely associated<br />

with transport emissions, are greenhouse gas<br />

substances too (GAP 2008). Win-win integrated<br />

strategies to address both issues are needed<br />

to succeed in fostering sustainable transport<br />

interventions at the local level.<br />

Sustainable transport interventions are needed<br />

to enhance accessibility rather than just mobility.<br />

Enhanced accessibility is essential to continued<br />

economic progress. The transportation system<br />

and its context need to be addressed as a whole<br />

to develop effective solutions. Transportation<br />

services enable economic development by<br />

facilitating the mobility of people and goods.<br />

Economic growth, which is reflected in increased<br />

industrial activities and income consumption,<br />

creates transport impacts. Transport can produce<br />

negative economic, social and environmental<br />

impacts, as well as positive externalities. Left<br />

unrestrained, these impacts and its causes can<br />

inhibit transport services, thus compromising<br />

sustainable development (Molina et al., 2002,<br />

WBCSD 2007).<br />

112<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


For the vast majority of urban areas in developing<br />

countries, public transport continues to be the<br />

largest mode of transportation. A combination of<br />

economic growth, high motorization rates, poor<br />

quality public transport systems, exacerbated<br />

metropolitan sprawls and replication of<br />

unsustainable life-styles is rapidly changing this<br />

panorama. An accelerated expansion in both the<br />

number and use of low-capacity modes (such<br />

as private cars or motorcycles) and a drastic<br />

diminution of the ability of public transport<br />

systems to satisfy overwhelming mobility demands<br />

are generally observed in cities in developing<br />

countries.<br />

There are important barriers that need to be<br />

overcome if we are to succeed in moving on to<br />

more sustainable transport patterns. Nations<br />

and cities need support to overcome substantial<br />

barriers. Support is needed to develop visions<br />

and policy frameworks, develop more integrated<br />

programs, strengthen and integrate transport<br />

agencies and land-use planning agencies,<br />

and overcome institutional fragmentation by<br />

improving mechanisms between transport,<br />

environment and urban planning.<br />

There is also a need to develop the capacities<br />

of transport operators, as well as to improve<br />

business conditions to implement sustainable<br />

transport practices. More complete regulatory<br />

frameworks and their en<strong>for</strong>cement can create<br />

incentives <strong>for</strong> private sector investments. Cleaner<br />

technologies and alternative fuels require good<br />

business models, regulations and incentives.<br />

More appropriate priority settings could lead<br />

to improved finance to support sustainable<br />

transport interventions.<br />

Improved and scaled up finance instruments are<br />

needed to mitigate GHG and achieve multiple<br />

co-benefits by fostering sustainable transport in<br />

developing countries. There is a growing consensus<br />

that the Clean Development Mechanism (<strong>CDM</strong>)<br />

in its current <strong>for</strong>m has not sufficiently effective so<br />

far <strong>for</strong> achieving this purpose. It has been found<br />

that it is possible to introduce innovations under<br />

the current framework to improve the <strong>CDM</strong> as it<br />

applies <strong>for</strong> transport. Nevertheless, there is a need<br />

to develop improved financial and other policy<br />

instruments if the <strong>for</strong>thcoming global agreements<br />

on climate change are to be effective to addressing<br />

the urgent transport sector challenges.<br />

Now is the time <strong>for</strong> the international community<br />

to look back and review the per<strong>for</strong>mance and<br />

experiences in applying the <strong>CDM</strong> to the transport<br />

sector and consider decisions to be made to<br />

either improve the mechanism and/or develop<br />

alternative instruments <strong>for</strong> the <strong>new</strong> climate<br />

change regime after 2012.<br />

To this end, the paper first provides an overview<br />

of an ongoing participatory process to develop<br />

a strategy to improve <strong>CDM</strong> and to scale-up<br />

international finance instruments to foster<br />

sustainable urban transport. It then assesses<br />

the per<strong>for</strong>mance of <strong>CDM</strong> transport projects and<br />

The transport sector is one of the largest and<br />

fastest growing GHG sources. Between 1970<br />

and 2004, global GHG emissions from the<br />

transport sector increased by 120% globally,<br />

reaching 6.4 GTCO2-eq (13.4% of the total).<br />

identifies key issues limiting its development,<br />

<strong>including</strong> both achievements and challenges.<br />

It also identifies opportunities <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> to be<br />

improved under the current framework, as well as<br />

expectations <strong>for</strong> the <strong>new</strong> climate change regime<br />

Finance <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Urban Transport<br />

113<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


after 2012. Finally, proposals on the scaling-up of<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> are discussed and some initial thoughts<br />

considered.<br />

Building a strategy to improve <strong>CDM</strong><br />

and to scale-up finance to foster<br />

Sustainable Urban Transport<br />

For the first time, an international multistakeholder<br />

ef<strong>for</strong>t is underway to build a<br />

consensus on a strategy <strong>for</strong>: a) making <strong>CDM</strong> a more<br />

viable tool to finance transport interventions;<br />

and b) to ensure the development of improved<br />

clean transport funding mechanisms under<br />

the <strong>for</strong>thcoming climate change negotiations.<br />

Representatives from Designated National<br />

Authorities, Designated Operating Entities,<br />

International Development Agencies, investors,<br />

transport operators, transportation agencies<br />

and non-governmental organizations, as well as<br />

transport and environment experts from Asia,<br />

Europe, Latin America and North America, are<br />

participating in this ef<strong>for</strong>t, which has been led<br />

by the Clean Air Institute, with support from the<br />

Carbon Fund Assist Program (CF-Assist).<br />

The current project-based approach <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>CDM</strong> is having a limited impact on the<br />

transportation sector…… Developing<br />

methodologies to capture accurately the<br />

complexities of urban transport, at the<br />

project level, has proved to be very complex,<br />

time-consuming and costly.<br />

The aim is to identify the decisions and actions<br />

necessary to enhance the effectiveness of <strong>CDM</strong><br />

in the transportation sector, and to propose<br />

an action plan <strong>for</strong> strengthening the overall<br />

framework <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong> 2012 and beyond.<br />

In general terms, this has consisted in a review<br />

of the <strong>CDM</strong> framework as related to projects, a<br />

consultation meeting held in Washington DC,<br />

and a <strong>CDM</strong> & Transport workshop held in Berlin<br />

in June 2008.<br />

Nearly 60 participants representing a broad<br />

spectrum of carbon finance stakeholders were<br />

involved in the consultation process. In addition,<br />

the Clean Air Institute consulted with nearly 25<br />

international experts, <strong>including</strong> international<br />

transport and environmental specialists, staff<br />

from the World Bank and the Inter-American<br />

Development Bank, project proponents, bilateral<br />

agencies and private-sector organizations, as well<br />

as a <strong>CDM</strong> Methodology Panel member.<br />

Some of the major findings to emerge from these<br />

processes are as follows:<br />

• The current project-based approach <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>CDM</strong> is having a limited impact on the<br />

transportation sector. Moreover, even if<br />

successful, the impact of individual <strong>CDM</strong><br />

transport projects is relatively small. Developing<br />

methodologies to capture accurately<br />

the complexities of urban transport, at the<br />

project level, has proved to be very complex,<br />

time-consuming and costly.<br />

• The determinations of the baseline scenario<br />

and the demonstration of additionality<br />

are the most significant barriers to developing<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> transport projects. There are<br />

also significant challenges regarding the<br />

reliability and availability of data, as well<br />

as the capacity <strong>for</strong> data collection in the<br />

transport sector.<br />

• The current <strong>CDM</strong> process should be made<br />

more attractive <strong>for</strong> project proponents and<br />

investors by broadening its scope, simpli-<br />

114<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


fying and improving data collection and<br />

methodologies, and removing or minimizing<br />

barriers, such as the additionality requirement.<br />

For example, there is the possibility<br />

to use the “first of its kind” approach<br />

(an existing provision under the current<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> procedure) to meet the additionality<br />

requirement.<br />

• Any ef<strong>for</strong>t to improve the existing <strong>CDM</strong><br />

program should serve as a basis <strong>for</strong> creating<br />

more effective instruments <strong>for</strong> the<br />

transport sector <strong>for</strong> post-2012. In general,<br />

the <strong>new</strong> instruments should be top-down,<br />

of broad scale, specific to the transport<br />

sector, account better <strong>for</strong> co-benefits, and<br />

foster the incorporation of climate change<br />

considerations into local and national policies<br />

and policy instruments.<br />

As a result of these findings, a Strategy on <strong>CDM</strong><br />

and Transport (the Berlin Strategy <strong>for</strong> short) was<br />

proposed. The Berlin Strategy is organized in two<br />

parts. First, a set of re<strong>for</strong>ms and <strong>new</strong> programs<br />

should be adopted within the existing <strong>CDM</strong><br />

framework. Secondly, <strong>new</strong> carbon finance instruments<br />

should be developed <strong>for</strong> the post-Kyoto<br />

era.<br />

Since Berlin, stakeholders have continued to meet<br />

and are moving <strong>for</strong>ward, using the Berlin Strategy<br />

as the foundation to persuade the Conference<br />

of Parties (COP) to improve the ability of the<br />

transport sector to receive carbon financing.<br />

As an example, the Clean Air Institute (CAI)<br />

recently participated in the Asian Development<br />

Bank Transport Forum, which was held in Manila<br />

from September 8-12, 2008. During that week,<br />

discussions were held with key stakeholders<br />

regarding the recommendations related to<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> and transport and how to translate those<br />

recommendations into action. As a result of those<br />

discussions, the strategy developed in Berlin was<br />

““…the present system of mobility is not<br />

sustainable, nor is it likely to become so<br />

if present trends continue. Societies need<br />

to act to alter their direction. This is true,<br />

in particular, if mobility is to be made<br />

sustainable in the developing world.”<br />

World Business Council <strong>for</strong><br />

Sustainable Development<br />

World Business Council <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development<br />

enhanced and then presented at the last day of<br />

the Forum.<br />

There is a consensus among stakeholders about<br />

the importance of submitting the Berlin strategy<br />

outlined above at COP 14 to be held in Poznan<br />

in December 2008. In order to be discussed and<br />

adopted by the COP 14, the Berlin Strategy is in<br />

the process of being translated into a proposed<br />

draft decision document containing the necessary<br />

directives to be issued. Furthermore, the<br />

decision document is intended to contribute<br />

<strong>for</strong> discussions to be held in the COP 15 in<br />

Copenhagen in 2009, where a <strong>new</strong> climate<br />

change framework is to be discussed.<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> transport projects and methodologies<br />

Transportation was set as a priority <strong>for</strong> the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> by the COP 10 held in Buenos Aires in<br />

2003. Un<strong>for</strong>tunately, four years after COP 10,<br />

transport is still not well represented in the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project portfolio. Of the roughly 1191 <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Finance <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Urban Transport<br />

115<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


projects registered by November 2008 according<br />

to the UNEP Risø Pipeline (see http://www.<br />

cdmpipeline.org), there are only two involving<br />

urban transport:<br />

• The first project to be registered was Trans-<br />

Milenio (Phase II to IV), which is a Bus Rapid<br />

Transit System (BRT). A BRT is a highcapacity<br />

bus system that delivers efficient,<br />

safe, rapid services through dedicated<br />

lanes, rapid boarding, enclosed stations,<br />

real-time in<strong>for</strong>mation displays, etc.<br />

• The second transport project activity to be<br />

registered under the <strong>CDM</strong> is a small-scale<br />

project in India using the AMS-III-C methodology.<br />

The Delhi Metro Rail Corporation<br />

installed low GHG-emitting rolling stock<br />

(Metro locomotives and coaches), which<br />

have a regenerative braking system that improves<br />

energy efficiency.<br />

Table 1 provides additional in<strong>for</strong>mation of these<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>-registered projects.<br />

Currently, five transportation-sector methodologies<br />

have been approved by the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive<br />

Board, which are shown in Table 2. There are still<br />

no <strong>CDM</strong> projects approved <strong>for</strong> three of these five<br />

methodologies.<br />

There appears to be a growing consensus that the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>, as currently structured, is not well suited<br />

as a financing mechanism <strong>for</strong> sustainable urban<br />

transportation in developing countries.<br />

Table 1<br />

Public Transport <strong>CDM</strong> Projects Registered by the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board<br />

Registration<br />

date<br />

Description<br />

Methodology<br />

and scale<br />

Host<br />

Parties<br />

Other<br />

parties<br />

Reductions<br />

Ton/year<br />

07 Dec 06 BRT Bogotá,<br />

Colombia:<br />

TransMilenio Phase<br />

II to IV.<br />

AM0031<br />

(large scale)<br />

Colombia<br />

Switzerland<br />

Netherlands<br />

246,563<br />

29 Dec 07 Installation of Low<br />

Green House Gases<br />

(GHG) emitting<br />

rolling stock cars in<br />

metro system<br />

AMS-III-C<br />

(small scale)<br />

India Japan 41,160<br />

Total emissions reduced (tons/year) 287,723<br />

Source: <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board.<br />

116<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Table 2<br />

Transport Sector Methodologies approved by the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board<br />

Methodology<br />

Number<br />

Description<br />

AM0031<br />

(large scale)<br />

Applicable <strong>for</strong> the construction and operation of a BRT system <strong>for</strong> urban road-based<br />

transport, as well as extensions of existing BRT systems. The BRT methodology is the only<br />

large-scale methodology in the transport sector.<br />

AM0047<br />

(large scale)<br />

Production of biodiesel based on waste oils and/or waste fats from biogenic origin <strong>for</strong> use<br />

as fuel – Version 2<br />

AMS-III-C<br />

(small scale)<br />

“Emissions Reduction by Low GHG Emitting Vehicles”<br />

AMS-III.T<br />

(small scale)<br />

“Plant Oil Production and Use <strong>for</strong> Transport Application”<br />

AMS-III.S<br />

(small scale)<br />

“Introduction of Low Emission Vehicles to Commercial Vehicle Fleets.”<br />

Source: <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board.<br />

Key Barriers to <strong>CDM</strong> Project Development<br />

Two proximate types of reasons explain the lack<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong> projects in the transport sector:<br />

1. It is much more complex to deal with diffuse<br />

transport-sector emissions than with<br />

stationary sources. Moreover, in the transport<br />

sector, there are different types of<br />

sources, multiple actors and emissions,<br />

which depend on utilization conditions.<br />

2. The current <strong>CDM</strong> procedures are very complex<br />

and not well adapted to the sector.<br />

For a project to be eligible, it has to demonstrate<br />

that is able to achieve “real, measurable and<br />

additional reductions”. For a project to be<br />

registered, the project proponents should<br />

(Dalkman, 2007):<br />

• Set a baseline, which is the scenario representing<br />

the greenhouse gas emissions<br />

that would occur in the absence of the proposed<br />

project activity.<br />

• Prove project additionality, which implies<br />

that project proponents should demonstrate<br />

that the emissions reductions<br />

achieved are proved to be additional to any<br />

that would occur in the absence of the certified<br />

project activity.<br />

• Identify and calculate leakage, which<br />

should describe the net change in green-<br />

Finance <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Urban Transport<br />

117<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


house gas emissions which occurs outside<br />

the project boundary, and which is measurable<br />

and attributable to the <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activity.<br />

Setting the project baseline and proving<br />

additionality are difficult tasks because it is<br />

hard to demonstrate that a transport project is<br />

being implemented because of climate change<br />

considerations. First, it must be demonstrated<br />

that, within the project activity, GHG emissions<br />

are reduced to a level below what would have<br />

occurred in a “business as usual” situation.<br />

Then, a test must be run to identify the financial<br />

barriers that would prevent the implementation<br />

of the proposed project activity. But the financial<br />

impact of the <strong>CDM</strong> registration is very limited,<br />

and the results of the barrier analysis are<br />

usually not considered convincing because the<br />

carbon credits usually represent less than 2%<br />

of the infrastructure investment. Under these<br />

circumstances, in most cases there are difficulties<br />

in demonstrating that a project would not have<br />

proceeded without <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

In addition, there are also significant challenges<br />

regarding the reliability and availability of data,<br />

as well as the capacity <strong>for</strong> data collection in the<br />

…the financial impact of the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

registration is very limited, and the results<br />

of the barrier analysis are usually not<br />

considered convincing because the carbon<br />

credits usually represent less than 2% of<br />

the infrastructure investment. Under these<br />

circumstances, in most cases there are<br />

difficulties in demonstrating that a project<br />

would not have proceeded without <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

transport sector. Studies are proportionally<br />

expen sive compared to project costs. In some<br />

cases, the data required is limited or even does not<br />

exist. There also are complexities associated with<br />

estimating key indicators, such as projections of<br />

the number of passengers to be transported or<br />

the expected mode switch.<br />

Data complexities are exacerbated in projects that<br />

address fundamental structural changes such as<br />

infrastructure projects. These challenges could<br />

create overwhelming barriers to <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

development in the vast majority of developing<br />

countries, especially those with poor data and<br />

low experience and capacity (Barías et al., 2005;<br />

Dalkmann et al., 2007).<br />

Opportunities <strong>for</strong> improvement<br />

within existing <strong>CDM</strong> framework<br />

The current project-based approach <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> is<br />

having a limited impact on the transportation<br />

sector. Developing methodologies to capture<br />

accurately the complexities of urban transport<br />

at the project level has proved to be very<br />

time-consuming and costly. Moreover, even<br />

if successful, the impact of individual <strong>CDM</strong><br />

transport projects is relatively small. Attempting to<br />

measure emissions reductions at the project level<br />

is narrowly focused and prone to measurement<br />

errors, and thus not an appropriate approach <strong>for</strong><br />

the transport sector.<br />

Suggestions <strong>for</strong> improving the <strong>CDM</strong> as it relates<br />

to transport resulting from this international<br />

ef<strong>for</strong>t range from pursuing innovations within<br />

the existing <strong>CDM</strong> framework to developing<br />

programmatic and sectoral approaches, and<br />

creating an improved mechanism post-2012.<br />

In general, the current <strong>CDM</strong> process should be<br />

made more attractive <strong>for</strong> project proponents and<br />

118<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


investors by broadening its scope, simplifying and<br />

improving data collection and methodologies,<br />

and removing or minimizing barriers, such as the<br />

additionality requirement.<br />

It is possible to use the existing “first of its kind”<br />

approach to meeting the additionality requirement.<br />

Under “first of its kind,” a <strong>new</strong> type of project or<br />

approach can be deemed to meet the additionality<br />

requirement if no (or limited) project activity of<br />

its type is operational in the region or country.<br />

For example, relatively few cities have extensive<br />

BRT networks, and a convincing argument can be<br />

made that a certain number of <strong>new</strong> BRT projects<br />

could be deemed “first of their kind.”<br />

The “first of its kind” approach should be pursued<br />

<strong>for</strong> the transport sector and presented to the<br />

Methodologies Panel. There are significant issues<br />

regarding how to implement the “first of<br />

its kind” approach, <strong>including</strong> an estimate of<br />

baselines <strong>for</strong> each project, and these issues<br />

should be addressed promptly <strong>for</strong> discussion<br />

with the Methodology Panel.<br />

Developing programmatic and<br />

sectoral approaches<br />

A Program of Activities (PoA) is made up of <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Programme Activities (CPAs). CPAs are similar<br />

to project activities that: a) apply the same<br />

approved baseline and monitoring methodology;<br />

and b) involve one type of technology or set of<br />

interrelated measures. Multiple CPAs can be<br />

included under a PoA at the time of registration,<br />

and additional CPAs can be added at any point in<br />

the life of the PoA.<br />

The PoA has its origins in a decision of the COP/<br />

MOP that local/regional/national policies or<br />

standards cannot be considered as <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activities, but that project activities under a PoA<br />

Program of Activities<br />

A Programme of Activities (PoA)<br />

-often called Programmatic <strong>CDM</strong>)- is:<br />

• a voluntary action<br />

• coordinated by a private or public entity<br />

• implementing a policy/measure or stated goal (i.e.<br />

incentive schemes and voluntary programmes),<br />

• resulting in mensurable GHG emission reductions<br />

or avoidance that are additional to any that would<br />

occur in the absence of the PoA.<br />

Source: http://cdmrulebook.org/pageID/452http://cdmrulebook.org/<br />

can be registered as a single <strong>CDM</strong> project activity,<br />

provided that:<br />

• approved baseline and monitoring methodologies<br />

are used that, inter alia,<br />

• define the appropriate boundary, avoid<br />

double-counting and account <strong>for</strong> leakage,<br />

• ensuring that the emission reductions are<br />

real, measurable and verifiable, and additional<br />

to any that would occur in the absence<br />

of the project activity<br />

The approval of programmatic projects currently<br />

appears to be as complicated as the project-based<br />

approach, and additionality continues to be a barrier.<br />

An improved standard transport methodology<br />

could be developed <strong>for</strong> its application to a PoA. The<br />

implementation of the programmatic approach<br />

<strong>for</strong> transport should simplify data requirements,<br />

improve data collection, and minimize barriers<br />

such as the additionality requirement. There<br />

is a need to explore further how to design a<br />

POA consisting of individual projects under<br />

Finance <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Urban Transport<br />

119<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


an integrated sustainable transport program<br />

approach, such as public transport pedestrian<br />

and bicycle improvements, improved land use,<br />

transport demand management and freight<br />

management, as well as technology and fuel<br />

improvements.<br />

The transition from the current project-based<br />

approach to a broader programmatic or sectoral<br />

approach should be accomplished in phases. For<br />

example, the first phase could be a methodology<br />

applied to the public transport system of a city.<br />

Once a methodology has been verified, other<br />

transport programs or systems could be added to<br />

the methodology.<br />

Berlin Strategy: Improving <strong>CDM</strong> and<br />

scaling up financial instruments<br />

A two-part strategy is proposed and should be<br />

pursued in parallel (see Figure 1). First, a set of<br />

re<strong>for</strong>ms and <strong>new</strong> programs should be adopted<br />

Figure 1.<br />

Berlin Strategy: Improving <strong>CDM</strong> as a first step to scale up Carbon Finance Sustainable Urban Transport<br />

120<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


within the existing <strong>CDM</strong> framework. These<br />

re<strong>for</strong>ms and programs should be designed to:<br />

a) enhance the ability of <strong>CDM</strong> as an instrument<br />

to promote sustainable transport interventions;<br />

and b) improve the ability of project proponents<br />

to successfully pursue transport <strong>CDM</strong> projects.<br />

Secondly, a <strong>new</strong> mechanism should be developed<br />

<strong>for</strong> the post-Kyoto era that is specific to the<br />

transport sector; uses a broad scale rather<br />

than a project-specific methodology; takes into<br />

account the co-benefits of transport projects,<br />

such as improved air quality, human health, and<br />

economic opportunity; and encourages cities<br />

to link local transport planning with planning<br />

<strong>for</strong> greenhouse gas emissions reductions, perhaps<br />

through a combination of regulatory<br />

requirements and incentives.<br />

A three-phase program could be implemented to<br />

facilitate the actuation of this two-part strategy.<br />

In Phase I, a program of activities would be<br />

developed under the existing <strong>CDM</strong> framework<br />

and a standardized methodology would be<br />

applied to that program, taking advantage of<br />

the “first of its kind” methodology to meet the<br />

additionality test. A limited number of cities<br />

would be selected to pilot the methodology. A<br />

technical assistance program would be created<br />

to support the development of better baselines<br />

and monitoring capabilities, <strong>including</strong> data<br />

collection and management.<br />

In Phase II, more detailed data would be<br />

collected and data gaps identified in the pilot<br />

cities. International financial organizations<br />

would collaborate to begin integrating the<br />

methodological framework into lending practices,<br />

and cities would be encouraged to begin<br />

integrating the methodology into their transport<br />

planning. An international fund to support data<br />

collection, tools development, mitigation options,<br />

research and mainstream should be established<br />

to support these ef<strong>for</strong>ts.<br />

In Phase III, the results from the pilot cities would<br />

be validated. Assuming successful validation,<br />

methodological guidelines would be developed<br />

<strong>for</strong> use by other cities. Moreover, lessons learned<br />

from the program would be used to develop<br />

recommendations <strong>for</strong> approval by the COP and/<br />

or the Executive Board post-2012.<br />

Scaling-up finance to foster<br />

sustainable urban transport<br />

The major challenges of the <strong>new</strong> global agreement<br />

on climate change to be discussed at the COP 15<br />

in Copenhagen by the end of 2009 are the role<br />

that developing countries will play in the global<br />

mitigation ef<strong>for</strong>t and the adoption of appropriate<br />

financing mechanisms (DEFRA 2008).<br />

According to the UNFCCC, to get global emissions<br />

in 2030 back to today’s levels, the additional<br />

investment and financial flows (I&FF) required<br />

are estimated to be around US$200-210 billion.<br />

The transport sector will require 42-44% of this<br />

I&FF (UNFCCC 2007).<br />

Instruments like <strong>CDM</strong> in its current <strong>for</strong>m appear<br />

to be insufficient to reach these funding<br />

requirements, since they lack the scale needed<br />

by several orders of magnitude. There are claims<br />

that traditional sources of funding, like the funds<br />

administered by the GEF, are inadequate <strong>for</strong><br />

this purpose because “they fail to link funding<br />

with per<strong>for</strong>mance or success; they are typically<br />

slow and cumbersome; and they lack the scale<br />

necessary” (DEFRA 2008).<br />

Scaling up the magnitude requires significantly<br />

broadening the scope of policy instruments to<br />

address climate change issues. Among other<br />

Finance <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Urban Transport<br />

121<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Box 1<br />

Sectoral Approach Models<br />

The IEA has identified four models of sectoral approaches:<br />

1. No-lose sectoral targets and crediting<br />

mechanism. Developing countries adopt<br />

non-binding quantitative sectoral goals. Excess<br />

emission reductions are eligible as credits<br />

to be sold to industrialized countries to help<br />

them meet their fixed and binding targets.<br />

2. SDPAMs or policy-based instruments . Sectorspecific<br />

policies and measures in developing<br />

countries that have sustainable development<br />

as primary objective (SD-PAMs). It provides<br />

funding <strong>for</strong> SD-PAMs that reduce emissions<br />

beyond Business As Usual. It should be done<br />

with measurable, reportable and verifiable<br />

(MRV) actions. Binding or non-binding<br />

3. Transnational sectoral agreements. Transational<br />

agreement <strong>for</strong> a given industry<br />

The substance of these agreements is the<br />

adoption of quantitative and/or qualitative<br />

goals. This model is oriented to foster concerted<br />

Research and Development (R&D) ef<strong>for</strong>t.<br />

urgent decisions, it is necessary to adopt a strategic<br />

program approach to low carbon investments,<br />

which has to be able to aggregate on-the-ground<br />

activities in an unprecedented manner.<br />

Any ef<strong>for</strong>t to improve the existing <strong>CDM</strong> program<br />

should serve as a basis <strong>for</strong> creating more effective<br />

instruments <strong>for</strong> the transport sector post-2012.<br />

In general, these instruments should be programoriented,<br />

of broad scale and not project-specific.<br />

The <strong>new</strong> instrument should:<br />

• Be specific to the transport sector rather<br />

than of broad applicability, as with the current<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

• Better account <strong>for</strong> national and local benefits<br />

and the project’s contribution to sustainable<br />

development.<br />

• Seek to integrate planning <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> projects<br />

with transport and urban planning <strong>for</strong><br />

cities by focusing on improving accessibility<br />

rather than just mobility.<br />

• Foster the incorporation of climate change<br />

considerations into local and national policies<br />

and policy instruments to encourage<br />

emissions reductions in the transport sector<br />

more strongly.<br />

The IEA has identified four models of sectoral<br />

instruments that in conjunction can help to scale<br />

up financing in those sectors and sources where<br />

an abatement potential exists in developing<br />

countries (see box 1). One of these models is<br />

the Sector No-Lose Targets (SNLT’s). SNLTs<br />

are conceived as a scaled-up carbon finance<br />

mechanism, major features of which are (DEFRA<br />

2008):<br />

• It is based on ‘cap and trade’ emissions trading<br />

schemes <strong>for</strong> industrialized countries,<br />

complemented by schemes that allow credits<br />

to be generated through emissions reductions<br />

and sink enhancement activities in developing<br />

countries.<br />

• Targets would be adopted voluntarily by some<br />

developing countries <strong>for</strong> particular sectors.<br />

The ‘no lose’ feature means that developing<br />

countries would not face compliance penalties<br />

if they did not meet their SNLTs.<br />

• Targets would be agreed as part of a quantitative<br />

multilateral agreement.<br />

• The concept of additionality would no longer<br />

apply because the fixed and binding targets<br />

of industrialized countries would be set in<br />

the light of the scale of credits that would be<br />

122<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


expected to be generated by SNLTs from developing<br />

countries.<br />

• So, SNLTs (and the credits that may stem from<br />

them) are explicitly accepted and factored<br />

into the elements of the overall agreement<br />

that set a quantitative emissions outcome.<br />

• It could adopt ‘compliance carbon’ crediting<br />

‘tools’ from the existing ‘regular’ projectbased<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> and now programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> to<br />

<strong>new</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> models such as sectoral or policy<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>, which can be applied to SNLTs.<br />

• It should be seen as part of a set of policy<br />

tools to support developing countries as a<br />

‘compliance carbon’ policy tool.<br />

• It can complement the other sectoral instruments,<br />

such as the SD-PAMs.<br />

Whether the SNLTs are to be feasible <strong>for</strong> the<br />

transport sector requires an in-depth analysis.<br />

As with other credit-based mechanisms it is<br />

necessary with SNLTs to establish a baseline<br />

and then to measure (and report and verify)<br />

per<strong>for</strong>mance against this.<br />

Towards a separate funding stream <strong>for</strong><br />

transport-sector climate mitigation actions<br />

The transport sector needs to improve its visibility<br />

at the climate negotiations and make a case <strong>for</strong><br />

a separate funding mechanism <strong>for</strong> mitigationrelated<br />

activities. This global transport climate<br />

change mitigation fund would pay <strong>for</strong> at least two<br />

types of work:<br />

1. Worldwide research particularly focused at<br />

the developing world to support an integrated<br />

evaluation of transport and spatial/<br />

urban policy options, as well as to monitor<br />

their implementation.<br />

2. Ample funding of activities to incorporate<br />

climate change mitigation and other cobenefit<br />

consideration as part of the regional<br />

and metropolitan planning, investment<br />

prioritization, long-term budgeting, etc.<br />

This funding should be independent from<br />

particular investment projects by international<br />

development agencies.<br />

Conclusions<br />

The purpose of <strong>CDM</strong> is not being achieved in<br />

the transport sector. There are opportunities to<br />

improve the effectiveness of <strong>CDM</strong> by broadening<br />

its scope and simplifying its rules.<br />

There is an urgent need to couple the institutional<br />

mechanisms of interaction between the North<br />

and the South on climate change mitigation, and<br />

the needs of the transport sector.<br />

The transport sector in particular should have<br />

a stronger seat at the table in Poznan and<br />

beyond. This could mean having a stronger<br />

push within national governments to 1) develop<br />

a better understanding of climate change within<br />

transport ministries, and 2) greater involvement<br />

of transport ministries at climate negotiations.<br />

Any ef<strong>for</strong>t to improve the existing <strong>CDM</strong><br />

program should serve as a basis <strong>for</strong><br />

creating more effective instruments <strong>for</strong> the<br />

transport sector post-2012. In general,<br />

these instruments should be programoriented,<br />

of broad scale and not projectspecific.<br />

For the first time, a group of multi-stakeholder<br />

representatives is joining ef<strong>for</strong>ts to improve the<br />

future of <strong>CDM</strong> as related to the transport sector.<br />

Finance <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Urban Transport<br />

123<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


In addition to <strong>CDM</strong>-related measures, there is<br />

an urgent need <strong>for</strong> international development<br />

organizations to establish sound instruments<br />

to prevent and reduce GHG emissions from<br />

transport investments. International financial<br />

organizations could play a key role by<br />

establishing such instruments and by changing<br />

lending practices to encourage more sustainable<br />

transportation projects.<br />

There is a strong desire <strong>for</strong> the World Bank or other<br />

international organizations to assume leadership<br />

and to make the appropriate investments to<br />

ensure that these re<strong>for</strong>ms are accomplished. Key<br />

stakeholders need to be actively involved in the<br />

development of these re<strong>for</strong>ms.<br />

Ultimately, the transport sector needs to have<br />

a higher profile in climate negotiations. The<br />

development of increasingly effective instruments<br />

<strong>for</strong> transport is essential to achieving climate<br />

goals.<br />

Sergio Sanchez is the Executive Director of the Clean Air<br />

Institute, a non-profit organization involved in global and<br />

Latin American projects and initiatives on both climate<br />

change and air quality. He has also consulted <strong>for</strong> international<br />

organizations, such as the World Bank, Pan American Health<br />

Organization, and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology.<br />

References<br />

Barías, Jose Luis, Jodi Browne, Eduardo Sanhueza, Erin Silsbe, Steve Winkelman,<br />

Chris Zegras, Jose Luis (2005): Getting on Track: Finding a Path<br />

<strong>for</strong> Transportation in the <strong>CDM</strong>. Final Report. International Institute <strong>for</strong><br />

Sustainable Development (IISD). Winnipeg, Manitoba, Canada. (http://<br />

www.iisd.org/publications/pub.aspx?id=690).<br />

Clean Air Institute (2007). Draft Clean Air Strategy <strong>for</strong> Latin America<br />

and the Caribbean. Washington DC. (http://www.cleanairnet.org/<br />

lac_en/1415/article-72110.html).<br />

Clean Air Institute (2008). Draft Report and Strategy to Improve the<br />

Effectiveness of <strong>CDM</strong> to Foster Sustainable Transportation. Prepared <strong>for</strong><br />

the Carbon Fund Assist Program of the World Bank Institute. Washington<br />

DC.<br />

Dalkmann, Holger, Wolfgang Sterk, Daniel Bongardt, Bettina Wittneben,<br />

Christian Baatz (2007): The Sectoral Clean Development Mechanism: A<br />

Contribution from a Sustainable Transport Perspective. JIKO Policy Paper.<br />

Wuppertal Institute <strong>for</strong> Climate, Environment and Energy. Wuppertal,<br />

Germany.<br />

Intergovernmental Panel of Climate Change (2007). Climate Change<br />

2007. Synthesis Report. An Assessment of the Intergovernmental Panel<br />

on Climate Change, Adopted section by section at IPCC Plenary XXVII.<br />

Valencia, Spain, 12-17 November 2007.<br />

Molina Mario, Molina Luisa et al (2002). Air Quality in the Mexico Megacity:<br />

An Integrated Assessment. Series: Alliance <strong>for</strong> Global Sustainability<br />

Bookseries , Vol. 2.<br />

UNFCCC (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change)<br />

(2008). Investment and Financial Flows to Address Climate Change.<br />

Bonn.<br />

Ward, Murray. Streck, Ch., Winkler, Harald, Jung, M., Hagemann, M.,<br />

Hoehne, N., O’Sullivan, R (2008). The Role of Sector No-Lose Targets in<br />

Scaling up Finance <strong>for</strong> Climate Change Mitigation Activities in Developing<br />

Countries. Department <strong>for</strong> Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (DEFRA).<br />

United Kingdom.<br />

World Resources Institute (2005). Navigating the numbers. Washington,<br />

D.C.<br />

Zegras, Christopher P. As if Kyoto mattered: The clean development<br />

mechanism and transportation. Energy Policy, Vol. 35, No. 10. (October<br />

2007), pp. 5136-5150.<br />

Contact: ssanchez@cleanairinstitute.org<br />

124<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Finance <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Urban Transport<br />

125<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


126<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Anne Arquit Niederberger, PhD<br />

Policy Solutions, USA & Switzerland’<br />

Scaling Up Energy Efficiency<br />

under the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Abstract:<br />

This paper analyses the barriers to end-use energy<br />

efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong>, presents elements of a<br />

<strong>new</strong> shared vision <strong>for</strong> a <strong>CDM</strong> that will encourage<br />

end-use energy efficiency and suggests necessary<br />

re<strong>for</strong>ms in the international climate framework that<br />

go beyond the traditional conception of <strong>CDM</strong><br />

re<strong>for</strong>m. For the <strong>CDM</strong> to achieve its dual mitigation<br />

and sustainable development objectives, the Parties<br />

to the UNFCCC can no longer be satisfied with the<br />

perfect environmental integrity of a zero-sum <strong>CDM</strong><br />

at the expense of real action on end-use efficiency.<br />

Nothing short of a global energy efficiency<br />

offensive is needed in Copenhagen in 2009.<br />

Whereas the Clean Development Mechanism<br />

(<strong>CDM</strong>) has proved effective with respect to the<br />

objective of assisting industrialized countries<br />

achieve compliance with their emission reduction<br />

commitments, a strategic vision of the <strong>CDM</strong> to<br />

address the drivers of greenhouse gas emissions<br />

growth and contribute to the sustainable<br />

development of poor countries is lacking.<br />

Furthermore, the <strong>CDM</strong> has been a disappointment<br />

<strong>for</strong> many developing countries. India, China,<br />

Brazil and Mexico host 75% of the total number<br />

of registered projects, whereas 90% of CERs<br />

have been issued to China, India, South Korea<br />

and Brazil. This concentration has left Least<br />

Developed Countries, Small Island Developing<br />

States and Sub-Saharan African countries<br />

with a very thin slice of the carbon market. Yet<br />

energy efficiency projects have huge potential<br />

127<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


in countries worldwide, <strong>including</strong> the poorest<br />

– and efficient use of energy may contribute to<br />

economic development and poverty alleviation. 1<br />

Nonetheless typically small and dispersed enduse<br />

efficiency projects face a number of barriers,<br />

both general and <strong>CDM</strong>-specific. As a result,<br />

only eighteen energy demand projects (Sectoral<br />

Scope 3) have been registered to date in only<br />

five different countries, representing 1.5% of<br />

all <strong>CDM</strong> projects and an even smaller share of<br />

issued CERs.2 This level of per<strong>for</strong>mance stands<br />

in stark contrast to mitigation scenarios, which<br />

typically ascribe a dominant share of mitigation<br />

in the coming decades to end-use efficiency. Action<br />

is clearly needed to scale up carbon finance<br />

<strong>for</strong> end-use efficiency.<br />

This paper analyses the barriers to end-use<br />

energy efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong> to date, presents<br />

elements of a <strong>new</strong> shared vision <strong>for</strong> a <strong>CDM</strong> that<br />

will encourage end-use energy efficiency and<br />

suggests necessary re<strong>for</strong>ms in the international<br />

framework that go far beyond the traditional<br />

conception of <strong>CDM</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m.<br />

The Bali Road Map process has yet to acknowledge<br />

clearly the significance of energy efficiency<br />

as a primary means of mainstreaming climate<br />

mitigation and capitalizing on global convergence<br />

in brokering an effective climate deal. The<br />

Copenhagen agreement must provide the foundation<br />

<strong>for</strong> a global energy efficiency offensive,<br />

with the <strong>CDM</strong> as only one tool.<br />

A Drop in the Bucket<br />

The Clean Development Mechanism has resulted<br />

in 1152 registered projects, <strong>for</strong> which 183 million<br />

certified emission reductions 3 (CERs) have<br />

been issued, as well as a pipeline of another<br />

2667 projects that are at the validation stage or<br />

have requested registration 4 (UNEP Risø <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Pipeline, 2008).<br />

With respect to end-use energy efficiency, the<br />

amount of CERs issued is miniscule compared<br />

to the vast savings potential. The amount of<br />

cumulative CERs expected to be issued through<br />

2012 from the end-use energy efficiency projects<br />

that have been registered to date under the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

is 9.68 million CERs 5 (Figure 1). In contrast, the<br />

International Energy Agency (IEA) has issued<br />

a series of 25 energy efficiency policy recommenda<br />

tions, which could save around 8.2 GtCO 2<br />

annually by 2030 (IEA, 2008). Even if we assume<br />

that all end-use efficiency projects currently in<br />

the pipeline will be registered and deliver CERs<br />

according to design specifications, the total<br />

cumulative emission reductions from end-use<br />

efficiency <strong>CDM</strong> through 2020 only amount to 72<br />

million tons of carbon dioxide.<br />

Taking China (the largest supplier of CERs)<br />

as an example, 90% of issued CERs stem from<br />

industrial HFC projects (UNEP Risø <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Pipeline, 2008). The <strong>CDM</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e has had<br />

very little documented impact on key drivers<br />

1 The most common energy-related issue raised in national<br />

MDG reports is energy efficiency, not re<strong>new</strong>able energy or access<br />

to energy (Takada and Fracchia, 2007).<br />

2 If we use the UNEP Risø <strong>CDM</strong> Pipeline end-use efficiency<br />

categories EE Household, EE Service and EE Industry (some of<br />

which correspond to other sectoral scopes), the fifty registered<br />

(plus project at validation) end-use efficiency projects represent<br />

just over 4% of all projects, but only 1.3% of expected CERs in<br />

2012, as a result of their typically small size (UNEP Risø <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Pipeline, September 2008).<br />

3 Each CER represents one ton of carbon dioxide equivalent<br />

greenhouse gas emissions reductions.<br />

4 Status as of 1 September 2008.<br />

5 Included are the UNEP Risø <strong>CDM</strong> Pipeline (2008) categories<br />

EE Household (3 registered projects), EE Industry (45<br />

registered projects) and EE Service (2 registered projects). If we<br />

consider the sectoral scope 3 (energy demand) category alone,<br />

only 18 projects have been approved, 9 rejected and a Request<br />

<strong>for</strong> Review submitted <strong>for</strong> two others.<br />

128<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Figure 1. Projected Cumulative CERs <strong>for</strong> Energy Efficiency<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> Projects in 2012 and 2020<br />

In the area of energy efficiency, the Government<br />

of China set a goal to reduce energy intensity per<br />

unit of GDP by 20% between 2006 and 2010.<br />

The government has begun to implement ten key<br />

energy-saving programmes. According to China’s<br />

National Climate Change Programme (CNCCP),<br />

these ten programmes are expected to result in<br />

550 million tons of CO 2<br />

reductions during the<br />

11 th Five-Year Plan (FYP) period (GOC, 2008).<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong> has contributed to only one of these<br />

programs, namely waste heat and gas (WHG)<br />

recovery and utilization. Of China’s 22 registered<br />

projects (which represent one-third of the global<br />

total), two projects have so far generated 768,000<br />

Data Source: UNEP RISØ <strong>CDM</strong> PIPELINEUNEP RISØ <strong>CDM</strong> PIPELINE<br />

(2008).<br />

of China’s greenhouse gas emissions growth, 6<br />

which, in light of ongoing standard-of-living<br />

improvements, can only be curbed through<br />

greater energy efficiency, the decarbonization<br />

of energy supply and economic restructuring.<br />

The additional investments into <strong>CDM</strong> and the<br />

resulting several hundred projects currently<br />

under implementation represent a limited<br />

contribution to the challenge of trans<strong>for</strong>ming<br />

the Chinese energy system, measured against<br />

China’s own energy policy goals and intentions<br />

to develop a low-carbon economy.<br />

6 With the available high-volume HFC destruction opportunities<br />

using methodology AM0001 already realized, the potential<br />

share of CERs from methane and carbon dioxide reduction<br />

projects in the Chinese pipeline is growing. Given the dominance<br />

of carbon dioxide in China’s GHG emissions inventory, as well<br />

as the typically better sustainability of energy efficiency and<br />

re<strong>new</strong>able energy projects that dominate the carbon dioxide<br />

reductions, this is a welcome development.<br />

…end-use efficiency projects face a number<br />

of barriers, both general and <strong>CDM</strong>-specific.<br />

As a result, only eighteen energy demand<br />

projects (Sectoral Scope 3) have been<br />

registered to date in only five different countries,<br />

representing 1.5% of all <strong>CDM</strong> projects and<br />

an even smaller share of issued CERs<br />

CERs 7 halfway through the 11 th FYP period (Table<br />

1). There has been little or no <strong>CDM</strong> activity in<br />

other key end-use areas, such as electric motor<br />

systems, industrial process efficiency, building<br />

energy efficiency or high-efficiency lighting,<br />

which are targeted <strong>for</strong> large energy savings.<br />

Similarly, the <strong>CDM</strong> is making only a minor<br />

contribution (less than 1%) to achieving the other<br />

targets set out in the CNCCP with the exception<br />

of wind power. Wind power has received a boost<br />

7 These two projects are expected to generate 34 million<br />

CERs by 2012 and nearly 80 million CERs by 2020. However,<br />

their issuance success (ratio of CERs actually issued to expected<br />

CERs according to the Project Design Document) has been only<br />

52% and 61% respectively (UNEP Risø <strong>CDM</strong> Pipeline, September<br />

2008).<br />

Scaling Up Energy Efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

129<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Table 1. China’s Emission Reduction Targets 2006-10 and <strong>CDM</strong> Contribution (as of 1 September 2008)<br />

Sector/Technology<br />

CNCCP Reduction Goal<br />

Issued CERs<br />

CO2e)<br />

(Mt<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> Contribution to<br />

Target (%)<br />

10 Key Energy Conservation Programs 550 Mt CO2 0.768 0.14<br />

Hydropower 500 Mt CO2 1.058 0.21<br />

Coal-bed and coal–mine methane 200 Mt CO2e 0.638 0.32<br />

Advanced thermal power generation 110 Mt CO2 0* *<br />

Other re<strong>new</strong>able energy (wind, solar,<br />

geothermal, tidal) 60 Mt CO2 2.401 4.00<br />

Biomass, biogas and liquid fuel 30 Mt CO2e 0.024 0.08<br />

Increased carbon sink (a<strong>for</strong>estation,<br />

re<strong>for</strong>estation, grassland/<strong>for</strong>est protection) 50 Mt CO2e 0 0<br />

* There is some overlap with the technologies mentioned in this category (particularly in the area of co-generation) with the energy conservation category<br />

(where we account <strong>for</strong> all CERs derived from use of waste heat or gas <strong>for</strong> self-generation). No CERs have been issued <strong>for</strong> other supply-side technologies<br />

mentioned in the CNCCP, such as small-scale distributed natural gas, advanced power transmission/ trans<strong>for</strong>mation/distribution technologies, or 600 MW<br />

or larger supercritical and ultra-supercritical combined-cycle thermal power plants.<br />

Sources: China’s National Climate Change Programme (2008); UNEP RISØ <strong>CDM</strong> PIPELINE (2008)<br />

from the landmark Re<strong>new</strong>able Energy Law of<br />

the Peoples’ Republic of China, which entered<br />

into <strong>for</strong>ce on 1 January 2006 (and subsequent<br />

regulations) and <strong>for</strong> which 2.4 million CERs<br />

have already been issued (representing 4% to<br />

achievement of the CNCCP target <strong>for</strong> “other”<br />

re<strong>new</strong>ables).<br />

Furthermore, <strong>CDM</strong> activities have had scarcely<br />

any impact on the main areas of concern in<br />

China, namely coal-fired power generation,<br />

energy-intensive industry (with the exception<br />

of WHG projects), buildings and transportation.<br />

So, the question is whether the <strong>CDM</strong> can play<br />

a more significant role in China’s and other<br />

countries’ transitions to an efficient and lowcarbon<br />

economy.<br />

The picture is similar <strong>for</strong> other developing<br />

countries. India recently issued its National<br />

Action Plan on Climate Change (GOI, 2008),<br />

which pointed to priority mitigation areas, such<br />

as solar thermal and PV generation, industrial<br />

energy efficiency and fuel switching, energy<br />

efficiency in the residential and commercial<br />

building sector, management of municipal solid<br />

waste, and promotion of urban public transport.<br />

Although the plan did not set national CO 2<br />

reduction targets <strong>for</strong> these priority areas, it is<br />

clear that the number of CERs issued to date is<br />

limited compared to the potential. Neither solar<br />

thermal and PV nor transport-sector projects<br />

have generated any CERs – and only a single<br />

small-scale project has been registered under<br />

each of these priority categories. Similarly, only<br />

2000 CERs have been issued <strong>for</strong> the single<br />

registered building efficiency project and<br />

76,000 CERs <strong>for</strong> one of the three registered<br />

landfill gas projects. Compared with other<br />

countries, there has been relatively greater <strong>CDM</strong><br />

activity in India’s industrial sector, both end-use<br />

efficiency and WHG projects. Nearly 6.5 million<br />

130<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


CERs have been issued from sixteen waste heat<br />

and gas recovery projects, predominantly in the<br />

iron and steel sector, 527,000 CERs from sixteen<br />

end-use efficiency projects – although these<br />

are predominantly small industrial efficiency<br />

projects with annual emission reductions of less<br />

than 30 kCERs – and 794,000 CERs from five<br />

fuel switch projects (four of which are industrial<br />

captive power plants).<br />

Barriers to End-Use Energy<br />

Efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

End-use energy efficiency is of particular interest<br />

in the context of developing country contributions<br />

to mitigation, since such activities can make an<br />

important contribution to economic and social<br />

development, while mitigating greenhouse gas<br />

and local pollutant emissions at relatively low cost.<br />

So why are these projects not being developed<br />

under the <strong>CDM</strong>? One reason is the design of the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> itself and how the <strong>CDM</strong> provisions are being<br />

interpreted and applied in practice.<br />

The Parties to the Kyoto Protocol have agreed<br />

that the <strong>CDM</strong> must result in emission reductions<br />

that are:<br />

• Additional: A <strong>CDM</strong> project activity is additional<br />

if anthropogenic emissions of<br />

greenhouse gases by sources are reduced<br />

below those that would have occurred in<br />

the absence of the registered <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activity.<br />

• Measurable and directly attributable: A<br />

Designated Operational Entity must certify<br />

that the project activity achieved the<br />

verified amount of reductions in anthropogenic<br />

emissions by sources of greenhouse<br />

gases.<br />

These rules treat the <strong>CDM</strong> as a zero sum game<br />

<strong>for</strong> the climate system at best, and are there<strong>for</strong>e<br />

Energy efficiency is often highly profitable on<br />

paper, and such projects have there<strong>for</strong>e had<br />

a tough time demonstrating additionality<br />

arising from financial and other barriers to<br />

the satisfaction of the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board<br />

not creating the necessary incentive <strong>for</strong> host<br />

countries to engage in the hard work of market<br />

trans<strong>for</strong>mation that is needed <strong>for</strong> sustained,<br />

large-scale change, such as introducing and<br />

rapidly updating mandatory equipment standards.<br />

Their interpretation and application has made it<br />

extremely difficult to leverage carbon finance <strong>for</strong><br />

energy efficiency projects, particularly dispersed<br />

end-use efficiency projects with documented<br />

sustainable development benefits, <strong>for</strong> a number of<br />

reasons: 8<br />

• Energy efficiency is often highly profitable<br />

on paper (Reddy and Balachandra, 2006),<br />

and such projects have there<strong>for</strong>e had a<br />

tough time demonstrating additionality<br />

arising from financial and other barriers<br />

to the satisfaction of the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive<br />

Board. In fact, most end-use efficiency<br />

projects would fail a classical investment<br />

analysis; however, they face other pervasive,<br />

well-documented barriers too. Many of the<br />

29 responses to the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board’s<br />

recent Call <strong>for</strong> Public Inputs on a draft<br />

proposal <strong>for</strong> an enhanced barrier test <strong>for</strong><br />

project activities that have potentially high<br />

profitability without CER revenues pointed<br />

to the need to promote energy efficiency<br />

projects under the <strong>CDM</strong>, not make it even<br />

more difficult to register them. 9<br />

8 Many of these issues have been raised previously (Arquit<br />

Niederberger and& Spalding-Fecher, 2006), but none has been<br />

adequately addressed.<br />

9 http://cdm.unfccc.int/public_inputs/2008/cers_rev/index.<br />

html<br />

Scaling Up Energy Efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

131<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Table 2. Application of Approved Energy Demand Methodologies<br />

Methodology<br />

Methodology<br />

Number of<br />

Title<br />

Available Since<br />

Reference #<br />

Registered Projects<br />

6 December 2004 AM0017<br />

Steam system efficiency improvements by replacing steam<br />

traps and returning condensate<br />

0<br />

6 December 2004 AM0018 Steam optimization systems 10<br />

25 February 2005 AM0020<br />

Baseline methodology <strong>for</strong> water-pumping efficiency<br />

improvements<br />

0<br />

16 February 2007 AM0046 Distribution of efficient light bulbs to households 0<br />

30 November 2007 AM0060<br />

Power saving through replacement by energy efficient<br />

chillers<br />

0<br />

16 May 2008 AM0068<br />

Methodology <strong>for</strong> improved energy efficiency by modifying<br />

ferroalloy production facility<br />

0<br />

1 November 2002 AMS II.C.<br />

Demand-side energy efficiency activities <strong>for</strong> specific<br />

technologies<br />

4*<br />

1 November 2002 AMS II.E. Energy efficiency and fuel-switching measures <strong>for</strong> buildings 5*<br />

22 October 2004 AMS II.F.<br />

Energy efficiency and fuel-switching measures <strong>for</strong><br />

agricultural facilities and activities<br />

0<br />

1 February 2008 AMS II.G.<br />

Energy Efficiency Measures in Thermal Applications of Non-<br />

Re<strong>new</strong>able Biomass<br />

0<br />

2 August 2008 AMS II.J. Demand-side activities <strong>for</strong> efficient lighting technologies 0<br />

*One project uses both AMS II.C. and AMS II.E.<br />

Source: UNFCCC <strong>CDM</strong> Database (http://cdm.unfccc.int/Projects/projsearch.html), status of approval of Sectoral Scope 3 methodologies and registration<br />

of projects applying these methodologies as of 30 July 2008. Note that some of the 31 projects that apply AMS II.D. (Sectoral Scope 4) also include<br />

end-use efficiency measures. Four additional large-scale methodologies in other sectoral scopes have been approved within the past year, but no registered<br />

project activities have made use of them.<br />

• Viable, widely applicable methodologies<br />

<strong>for</strong> end-use energy efficiency are lacking.<br />

As a result of the agreed “case-study”<br />

approach to methodology development,<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> modalities and procedures<br />

did not provide consistent top-down<br />

guidance <strong>for</strong> “good practice” regarding<br />

the key methodological issues that are<br />

crucial to all types of energy end-use<br />

efficiency activities. Conversely, it has<br />

been difficult to have methodologies<br />

approved by the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board<br />

that are based on “good practice”<br />

ener gy-saving quantification methods<br />

used in large, government-supervised<br />

energy efficiency programmes, such<br />

as those run by utility companies and<br />

funded by ratepayer money. As a result,<br />

there is a lack of viable methodologies<br />

to support the wide array of end-use<br />

efficiency project types. The available<br />

energy efficiency methodologies have<br />

either narrow applicability, have proved<br />

impossible to apply in practice (in the<br />

case of large-scale methodologies,<br />

Table 2) or have relied on project-level<br />

monitoring of individual pieces<br />

of equipment (in the case of smallscale<br />

methodologies), which is neither<br />

cost-effective nor practical in many<br />

circumstances and discourages system<br />

efficiency improvements that yield the<br />

greatest energy savings. 10 Another trend<br />

10 Several small-scale methodologies allow <strong>for</strong> a systems approach,<br />

but these have proved to be difficult to apply in practice<br />

(refer to Table 2). One positive <strong>new</strong> develop ment was the<br />

approval of AMS II.J. in August 2008, which allows <strong>for</strong> energy<br />

savings and greenhouse gas emission reductions from efficient<br />

132<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


is to burden existing small-scale end-use<br />

efficiency methodologies with additional<br />

requirements that would make them<br />

even less feasible under <strong>CDM</strong> Programs<br />

of Activities.<br />

• It is more difficult to determine baseline<br />

emissions <strong>for</strong> end-use efficiency activities<br />

– whether under retrofit or <strong>new</strong><br />

construction situations – than it is <strong>for</strong><br />

energy supply, fuel switching or other<br />

types of <strong>CDM</strong> project activities. This is<br />

partly due to the interpretation of <strong>CDM</strong><br />

authorities that trends in efficiency<br />

should be taken into account in the<br />

project baseline estimation, whereas this<br />

is not common practice in the energy<br />

efficiency world and would appear to<br />

contradict the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board’s<br />

own clarification that national and/or<br />

sectoral host-country policies to reduce<br />

emissions that were implemented after<br />

11 November 2001 need not be taken<br />

into account in developing a baseline<br />

scenario (<strong>CDM</strong>-EB, 2005).<br />

• Although leakage is defined as the net<br />

change of anthropogenic emissions by<br />

sources of greenhouse gases which occurs<br />

outside the project boundary, 11 the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Executive Board and its panels have not<br />

allowed project developers to account <strong>for</strong><br />

positive “spillover” effects, which can be<br />

particularly large <strong>for</strong> end-use efficiency<br />

programs. It is not uncommon <strong>for</strong> energy<br />

savings resulting from non-participants<br />

to exceed significantly the savings<br />

directly attributable to the programme<br />

lighting projects to be calculated using a “deemed” or “stipulated”<br />

savings approach, rather than monitoring the energy use<br />

and/or hours of operation of individual pieces of equipment in<br />

situ.<br />

11 UNFCCC document FCCC/KP/CMP/2005/8/Add.1<br />

(2006)<br />

participants themselves. A programme<br />

to offset the additional cost of energy<br />

efficient compact fluorescent lamps, <strong>for</strong><br />

example, not only makes them af<strong>for</strong>dable<br />

to programme participants, but can also<br />

result in economies of scale and retail<br />

price reductions that make the CFLs more<br />

af<strong>for</strong>dable – and quality improvements<br />

via bulk procurement specifications that<br />

make CFLs more attractive – to all market<br />

participants (IIEC, 2007).<br />

• The potential <strong>CDM</strong> incentive is insufficient<br />

to cover transaction costs <strong>for</strong><br />

typically small and often dispersed enduse<br />

efficiency actions.<br />

• The <strong>new</strong> Program of Activities (PoA)<br />

mode of <strong>CDM</strong> implementation, which<br />

was specifically designed to facilitate<br />

programmes to provide incentives <strong>for</strong><br />

dispersed, small-scale actions such as<br />

end-use efficiency (Hinostroza et al.,<br />

2007), has had a slow start since it was<br />

introduced over a year ago, with only one<br />

energy efficiency programme currently<br />

at the validation stage. In addition to the<br />

issues mentioned above, crucial market<br />

actors have been reluctant to embrace PoA<br />

– <strong>for</strong> example, DOEs are concerned about<br />

liability implications – and some DNAs<br />

have not created the legal framework<br />

to make it possible <strong>for</strong> them to issue<br />

letters of approval <strong>for</strong> PoA. Furthermore,<br />

potential PoA managing entities lack<br />

the necessary capacity. The recent <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Executive Board Call <strong>for</strong> Public Input<br />

on PoA yielded 36 submissions 12 that<br />

highlight PoA implementation challenges<br />

and suggest various re<strong>for</strong>ms.<br />

12 http://cdm.unfccc.int/public_inputs/2008/PoA/index.html<br />

Scaling Up Energy Efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

133<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


A more fundamental reason that end-use energy<br />

efficiency projects are not being developed under<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> is that such projects face multiple<br />

barriers – some of which cannot be overcome<br />

with CER revenues or investment alone. 13 Ironically,<br />

whereas demonstration of additionality<br />

has proved to be a stumbling block <strong>for</strong> energy<br />

efficiency methodologies and project activities,<br />

non-<strong>CDM</strong> barriers have prevented numerous<br />

energy efficiency opportunities with short<br />

payback periods from attracting <strong>CDM</strong> investment<br />

in the first place. Unless a comprehensive<br />

approach is taken to address typical barriers to<br />

end-use energy efficiency in national planning<br />

processes, whereby goals, policies and budgets<br />

are set, it will be difficult <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong> to unlock<br />

greater investment. This requires the adoption<br />

by host countries of a systematic framework <strong>for</strong><br />

integrating energy efficiency per<strong>for</strong>mance objectives<br />

into national poverty-reduction strategies<br />

(Arquit Niederberger, 2006).<br />

A more fundamental problem with the Kyoto<br />

Protocol and Bali Roadmap frameworks is that<br />

the approach has been climate-centric, with<br />

an emphasis on climate commitments, carbon<br />

markets and technology, rather than concentrating<br />

on how best to mainstream climatefriendly<br />

choices into development planning to<br />

maximize co-benefits and transition towards a<br />

sustainable society (Shukla, 2008). Focusing on<br />

mobilizing resources to overcome per<strong>for</strong>mance<br />

barriers related to the delivery of energy services<br />

(rather than the traditional energy supply optic)<br />

will ensure that not only are the technology and<br />

investment “hardware” issues addressed, but<br />

also the all-important “software” issues (such as<br />

public awareness, behavioural change, human<br />

13 Arquit Niederberger and Brunner (2007) offer an example<br />

of such multiple barriers in the area of high-efficiency industrial<br />

electric motor systems, which are responsible <strong>for</strong> about 40% of<br />

electricity demand worldwide.<br />

and institutional capacity; and policies and<br />

measures), which are currently being neglected.<br />

A Shared Vision <strong>for</strong> Energy Efficiency <strong>CDM</strong><br />

To trans<strong>for</strong>m markets so that the most energyefficient<br />

end-use equipment rapidly becomes<br />

business-as-usual in an ongoing process should<br />

be the major thrust of a global climate change<br />

mitigation strategy. These end-use technologies<br />

are available today. They have short payback<br />

periods, have the greatest potential <strong>for</strong> costeffective<br />

emissions reductions in the coming<br />

decades, can make decentralized re<strong>new</strong>able<br />

energy more viable, and have a range of sustainable<br />

development benefits. Achieving this vision will<br />

require coordinated ef<strong>for</strong>ts that go way beyond<br />

the traditional conception of <strong>CDM</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m,<br />

<strong>including</strong> giving top priority to energy efficiency<br />

in the Bali Action Plan, adopting a <strong>new</strong> strategic<br />

vision of the function that the <strong>CDM</strong> can play in<br />

assisting developing countries in contributing<br />

to climate mitigation (as opposed to merely<br />

lowering compliance costs <strong>for</strong> industrialized<br />

countries), and adopting improvements to the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> modalities and procedures.<br />

Bali Roadmap Process<br />

The negotiations have evolved from widespread<br />

early recognition of the importance of energy<br />

efficiency at the outset of the process to<br />

virtually no consideration of the importance of<br />

energy efficiency in the current negotiations.<br />

The discussions under the Ad Hoc Working<br />

Group on Further Commitments <strong>for</strong> Annex I<br />

Parties under the Kyoto Protocol (AWG-KP) are<br />

not considering energy efficiency to be one of<br />

the primary “means to reach emission reduction<br />

targets and ways to enhance their effectiveness and<br />

contribution to sustainable development”. Similarly,<br />

the related discussions on re<strong>for</strong>ming the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

134<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


only refer to energy efficiency as a possible “cobenefit”<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong> project activities, rather than<br />

<strong>including</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms to facilitate end-use energy<br />

efficiency project activities under the <strong>CDM</strong>. 14<br />

With regard to the Ad Hoc Working Group<br />

on Long-term Cooperative Action under the<br />

Convention, Parties have noted that:<br />

nationally appropriate mitigation actions by<br />

developing countries should be considered in the<br />

context of sustainable development, economic<br />

growth and poverty reduction, and that support<br />

<strong>for</strong> technology, financing and capacity-building<br />

was needed to enable Parties to enhance their<br />

action, <strong>including</strong> through actions in specific<br />

sectors, in particular re<strong>new</strong>able energy and<br />

energy efficiency. 15<br />

Whereas this summary of Parties’ views emphasizes<br />

both the importance of energy efficiency and<br />

the fact that climate mainstreaming can only<br />

be achieved with support <strong>for</strong> the on-the-ground<br />

ef<strong>for</strong>ts of developing countries, the negotiations<br />

have yet to conceptualize the necessary building<br />

blocks <strong>for</strong> energy efficiency.<br />

A massive scaling up of investment in end-use<br />

energy efficiency will require six billion decisionmakers<br />

to change their investment and habitual<br />

behaviour, which is a challenging undertaking,<br />

as illustrated in Box 1.<br />

To achieve this, the Copenhagen agreement will<br />

have to include specific provisions to promote<br />

market trans<strong>for</strong>mation beyond the narrow context<br />

of <strong>CDM</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m, <strong>including</strong> items such as:<br />

14 Overcoming the barriers to end-use efficiency under the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> was not included in the list of 26 possible <strong>CDM</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms in<br />

FCCC/KP/AWG/2008/L.12, despite widespread recognition of<br />

the problem (Arquit Niederberger, 2008), <strong>including</strong> by the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Executive Board.<br />

15 Energy efficiency was also identified as a sector <strong>for</strong> consideration<br />

in the context of cooperative sectoral approaches and<br />

sector-specific actions (FCCC/AWGLCA/2008/11).<br />

Box 1:<br />

What it Really Takes: “Motor-<br />

Fuelled” Efficiency Power Plant<br />

Making energy services more widely available by maximizing<br />

the efficiency of energy supply and end-use<br />

– an equivalent and preferable (or complementary)<br />

approach to building <strong>new</strong> power plants – will require<br />

investment decisions to shift from generators and<br />

utilities to the level of the end-user. Taking a typical<br />

“efficiency power plant” (EPP) fuelled by industrial<br />

electric motor system efficiency improvements as an<br />

example, the following rough calculations illustrate the<br />

scale of the endeavour:<br />

• Efficiency Power Plant capacity: 300 MWe<br />

• Potential efficiency improvement of motor<br />

system: 30%<br />

• Number of motor systems of 25 kWh each:<br />

40,000<br />

• Implementation examples:<br />

– tens of large factories<br />

– hundreds of municipal wastewater<br />

treatment plants<br />

– thousands of small factories<br />

This requires a scale of mobilization that is unprecedented,<br />

but the related work<strong>for</strong>ce development,<br />

financial engineering and regulatory and incentive<br />

framework challenges must be tackled, or energy efficiency<br />

opportunities with low or negative marginal<br />

abatement costs will not be realized.<br />

• Giving priority to energy efficiency in the<br />

shared vision <strong>for</strong> long-term cooperative<br />

action.<br />

• Launching a process to develop methodological<br />

guidance on the quantification and<br />

reporting of energy savings and greenhouse<br />

gas emission reductions resulting from<br />

Scaling Up Energy Efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

135<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Box 2:<br />

New Vision <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

in a Broader Policy Context<br />

• Regard the <strong>CDM</strong> as one source of investment or revenue to trans<strong>for</strong>m<br />

markets (and the carbon market more generally, as a means of<br />

delivering proper price signals), not a silver bullet. The Copenhagen<br />

agreement must include complementary means to remove barriers to<br />

end-use efficiency and market trans<strong>for</strong>mation.<br />

• Acknowledge that the rules <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong> as currently applied do<br />

not work <strong>for</strong> many types of very desirable end-use energy efficiency<br />

projects and programmes. Hence changes need to be made regarding<br />

additionality, methodologies and Programmes of Activities (PoAs).<br />

• Recognize that simple, robust and conservative methodological<br />

approaches to the quantification of energy savings and emission<br />

reductions from end-use efficiency ef<strong>for</strong>ts can ensure “real,<br />

measurable and long-term benefits related to the mitigation of climate<br />

change”. Such mitigation benefits would be greater than what is<br />

achieved under the current framework, with its emphasis on accuracy,<br />

precision and attribution at the expense of implementation.<br />

• Consider “free riders” as “early adopters” to be rewarded in the<br />

long-term ef<strong>for</strong>t to stimulate climate mitigation and encourage the<br />

maximization of market trans<strong>for</strong>mation, consistent with the two<br />

objectives of the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

• Encourage developing country Parties to establish realistic, yet<br />

aggressive goals <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> financing of poverty alleviation strategies,<br />

which would facilitate climate mainstreaming in development<br />

strategies and in<strong>for</strong>m buyers/investors of country priorities.<br />

• Mobilize concessional resources to support capacity-building,<br />

methodology development and business model development, e.g.<br />

training <strong>for</strong> potential PoA managing entities.<br />

• Create a qualified industry regulator made up of full-time staff (not<br />

acting as country or regional representatives) with a clear mandate<br />

and budget that will allow the body to deal with issues independently<br />

and on an ongoing basis.<br />

• Re-define the role of the <strong>CDM</strong> regulator to take more of a top-down<br />

approach to energy efficiency <strong>CDM</strong> evaluation by drawing on the<br />

vast expertise within the energy efficiency community and market<br />

participants engaging in commercial activity.<br />

policies, standards, codes, programmes,<br />

initiatives and projects, with special attention<br />

to energy efficiency.<br />

• Ensuring that energy efficiency becomes<br />

one of the key action areas <strong>for</strong> climate<br />

change mitigation by both developed and<br />

developing country Parties. This might include<br />

provisions related to:<br />

o Requirements to adopt National<br />

Energy Efficiency Action Plans and/<br />

or to undertake enhanced reporting<br />

on energy efficiency policies and<br />

measures (guidance on such plans<br />

and reporting would need to be<br />

developed).<br />

o Re<strong>for</strong>ms to the project-based<br />

mechanisms of the Kyoto Protocol<br />

that will allow carbon finance <strong>for</strong><br />

energy efficiency activities to be<br />

massively scaled up.<br />

o <strong>Mechanisms</strong> to ensure sufficient<br />

human, institutional and financial<br />

resources to raise public awareness,<br />

encourage behavioural change, and<br />

design, implement and en<strong>for</strong>ce the<br />

necessary policies and measures in<br />

the context of development strategies.<br />

o Commitment to implement<br />

specific energy efficiency policy<br />

recommendations, such as the<br />

IEA Energy Efficiency Policy<br />

Recommendations (IEA, 2008) and<br />

those of the Expert Group on Energy<br />

Efficiency (EGEE, 2007).<br />

o Technical work on subjects such as<br />

the harmonization of energy efficiency<br />

testing procedures, key per<strong>for</strong>mance<br />

indicators and benchmarking <strong>for</strong><br />

key sectors, stipulated savings, and<br />

quantification of energy savings.<br />

o International cooperation and<br />

partnerships.<br />

136<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


New Vision <strong>for</strong> the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Despite its stated dual objective, the <strong>CDM</strong> has<br />

come to be regarded as a zero sum game, with a<br />

focus on generating CERs <strong>for</strong> Annex I compliance.<br />

This is un<strong>for</strong>tunate, because the <strong>CDM</strong> could<br />

make a real contribution to greater mitigation<br />

by developing countries if the emphasis were<br />

shifted to maximizing <strong>CDM</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance with<br />

respect to market trans<strong>for</strong>mation and sustainable<br />

development goals. In the big picture, what<br />

goes on outside the project boundary in host<br />

countries with respect to drivers of emissions<br />

growth is much more important than what goes<br />

on inside it, yet the current <strong>CDM</strong> framework does<br />

not encourage positive spillovers or provide <strong>for</strong><br />

the evaluation of market effects.<br />

One of the prime objectives of <strong>CDM</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m,<br />

there<strong>for</strong>e, should be to strengthen the role of the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> in assisting developing countries to achieve<br />

sustainable development and contribute to the<br />

ultimate objective of the Convention. This will<br />

require action by host countries, <strong>for</strong> example,<br />

to develop plans to leverage carbon finance to<br />

implement their development strategies 16 (Arquit<br />

Niederberger, 2006). The financial mechanisms<br />

that emerge from the Bali Roadmap will need to<br />

support the necessary strategic, capacity, project<br />

and methodological development, particularly in<br />

poorer countries. The elements of a <strong>new</strong> vision<br />

<strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> are outlined in Box 2:<br />

But it will also require correcting some of the<br />

contradictory concepts and practices that have<br />

crept into the <strong>CDM</strong> rulebook. The <strong>CDM</strong> Executive<br />

Board provided a clarification that national<br />

16 An innovative approach taken by China was to require that<br />

the proceeds from <strong>CDM</strong> be shared with the government <strong>for</strong><br />

re-investment in climate change activities, with a greater share<br />

going to the government <strong>for</strong> non-priority project types.<br />

and/or sectoral host country policies to reduce<br />

emissions implemented after 11 November 2001<br />

need not be taken into account in developing<br />

a baseline scenario (<strong>CDM</strong>-EB, 2005). Yet the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> Methodology Panel and Small-Scale<br />

Working Group have repeatedly required that<br />

proposed <strong>new</strong> end-use efficiency methodologies<br />

specifically account <strong>for</strong> energy efficiency<br />

improvement trends and free-ridership in the<br />

baseline. This practice is in direct contradiction<br />

with the Board’s clarification, which further<br />

specified that the baseline scenario could refer<br />

to a hypothetical situation without the national<br />

A more fundamental reason that end-use energy<br />

efficiency projects are not being developed under<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> is that such projects face multiple<br />

barriers – some of which cannot be overcome<br />

with CER revenues or investment alone.<br />

and/or sectoral policies or regulations being<br />

in place. If the <strong>CDM</strong> is to assist developing<br />

countries in contributing to mitigation, then<br />

“early adopters” and progressive governments<br />

must be encouraged in the long-term ef<strong>for</strong>t to<br />

stimulate climate mitigation, not penalized.<br />

Treatment of leakage was mentioned above<br />

as another area of inconsistency. A further<br />

manifestation of this is that the Small-Scale<br />

Working Group has ruled that greenhouse gases<br />

as defined in Paragraph 1 of the UNFCCC, but not<br />

included in Annex A of the Kyoto Protocol (e.g.,<br />

CFCs, HCFCs), must be taken into account in<br />

considering leakage in so far as the <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activity results in an increase in emissions of<br />

those gases. This would appear to contradict the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board definition of leakage, which<br />

Scaling Up Energy Efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

137<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


efers to the net change of emissions. Replacing<br />

outdated refrigerators and space heating and<br />

cooling equipment that rely on fluorinated<br />

gases 17 as refrigerants (and as blowing agents in<br />

insulation material) offers opportunities <strong>for</strong> large<br />

additional greenhouse gas emission reductions,<br />

if proper incentives can be offered <strong>for</strong> end-of-life<br />

refrigerant recovery. There are 1.2 to 1.5 billion<br />

domestic refrigerators currently in service,<br />

representing an estimated bank of 100,000 tons<br />

of CFC-12, <strong>for</strong> example, and approximately 75%<br />

of their service refrigerant demand continues<br />

to be CFC-12 (UNEP/TEAP, 2006). Montreal<br />

Protocol (MP)–funded activities do not address<br />

post-production use of MP gases. As a result,<br />

although suitable alternatives have been available<br />

since the early 1990s, CFC refrigerators continue<br />

to be manufactured, sold and serviced because<br />

end users are excluded from MP support by the<br />

funding criteria. Other fluorinated gases (HFCs,<br />

HCFCs) used as substitutes also contribute<br />

significantly to the greenhouse effect. Allowing<br />

CERs to be generated <strong>for</strong> the reduction in<br />

CFCs and HCFCs at end-of-life could increase<br />

the financial viability of one subset of small<br />

energy efficiency projects with relatively high<br />

transaction costs and also address an important<br />

source of greenhouse gas emissions that is not<br />

covered by any international agreement. This<br />

could be done simply by considering these gases<br />

in the context of net leakage.<br />

It will also require greater attention to <strong>CDM</strong><br />

re<strong>for</strong>ms that are needed to scale up carbon<br />

finance <strong>for</strong> end-use efficiency actions. The lists<br />

of possible improvements to the <strong>CDM</strong> coming<br />

out of the August 2008 round of climate talks<br />

17 Industrial fluorinated gases include hydrofluorocarbons<br />

(HFCs) that fall under the Kyoto Protocol Annex A and chlorofluorocarbons<br />

(CFCs) and hydrochlorofluorocarbons (HCFCs)<br />

that fall under Paragraph 1 of the UNFCCC – all of which are<br />

greenhouse gases.<br />

in Accra included 26 suggestions to enhance the<br />

effectiveness of the <strong>CDM</strong> and its contribution<br />

to sustainable development and to protecting<br />

the climate system. 18 Yet, not a single suggestion<br />

addressed the documented challenges faced<br />

by end-use efficiency projects under the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

Clearly, there is a disjuncture between the<br />

emphasis placed on energy efficiency and<br />

re<strong>new</strong>able energy in the context of negotiations<br />

on developing country mitigation actions under<br />

the AWG-LCA, and the related <strong>CDM</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m<br />

discussions under the AWG-KP.<br />

Key <strong>CDM</strong> Re<strong>for</strong>ms Needed<br />

<strong>for</strong> Energy Efficiency<br />

The Executive Board continues to explore<br />

approaches to create a more enabling environment<br />

<strong>for</strong> implementing energy efficiency project<br />

activities under the <strong>CDM</strong> and has requested the<br />

secretariat to initiate work on ways of facilitating<br />

the registration of energy efficiency activities<br />

under <strong>CDM</strong> modalities and procedures. 19 Yet two<br />

recent suggestions by the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board<br />

are worrisome: (i) the draft <strong>CDM</strong> Validation &<br />

Verification Manual instructs DOEs to determine,<br />

in the course of project validation, “whether<br />

or not the project activity would have been<br />

undertaken without the incentive of the <strong>CDM</strong>”,<br />

which is quite a divergent concept from the way<br />

in which it is defined, namely “a <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activity is additional if anthropogenic emissions<br />

of greenhouse gases by sources are reduced<br />

below those that would have occurred in the<br />

absence of the registered <strong>CDM</strong> project activity”;<br />

and (ii) consideration of an “enhanced barrier<br />

test” <strong>for</strong> project activities that have a potentially<br />

high profitability, which could make it even<br />

18 FCCC/KP/AWG/2008/L.12<br />

19 See Annex 13 to the Report of the 41 st session of the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Executive Board <strong>for</strong> a status report.<br />

138<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


more difficult <strong>for</strong> energy efficiency activities to<br />

leverage carbon finance as discussed above.<br />

The demonstration of additionality of end-use<br />

energy efficiency projects or programmes has<br />

been one of the main barriers to methodology<br />

approval and <strong>CDM</strong> registration of such projects.<br />

Energy efficiency projects tend to have very short<br />

Figure 2. Motor System Investment Decisions Facing Plant<br />

Owners<br />

Discretionary Retrofit<br />

payback periods, primarily as a result of reduced<br />

energy costs (Arquit Niederberger and Brunner,<br />

2007), so they cannot typically demonstrate<br />

additionality on the basis of financial analysis.<br />

New ways of addressing additionality concerns<br />

<strong>for</strong> energy efficiency projects are needed. To<br />

begin with, it is important <strong>for</strong> additionality to be<br />

considered from the perspective of the technology<br />

end-user in the decision-making context in which<br />

he/she is operating, not some hypothetical ideal.<br />

The generic choices facing a plant owner can be<br />

illustrated using the example of industrial electric<br />

motor systems (Arquit Niederberger and Brunner,<br />

2007):<br />

Planned Replacement<br />

…the <strong>CDM</strong> has come to be regarded as a<br />

zero sum game, with a focus on generating<br />

CERs <strong>for</strong> Annex I compliance. This is<br />

un<strong>for</strong>tunate, because the <strong>CDM</strong> could make<br />

a real contribution to greater mitigation by<br />

developing countries if the emphasis were<br />

shifted to maximizing <strong>CDM</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance<br />

with respect to market trans<strong>for</strong>mation<br />

and sustainable development goals<br />

New Installation/Facility<br />

Source: Arquit Niederberger & Brunner (2007)<br />

• Discretionary retrofits can involve just<br />

the motor or the entire system. The<br />

basic choice facing an enterprise is the<br />

continued operation of existing motor<br />

(system) vs. retrofit with <strong>new</strong> equipment<br />

(Figure 2). The most plausible baseline<br />

is continued operation of the existing<br />

equipment, which has already been<br />

amorticized, since the alternative<br />

would result in additional investment<br />

costs, plant downtime, lost revenue and<br />

technology risks.<br />

Scaling Up Energy Efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

139<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


• Planned replacement is almost always<br />

only focused on the motor, core system<br />

or other discrete technology, as the<br />

entire system rarely fails all at once.<br />

The basic choice facing an enterprise<br />

at the time a motor fails is repair<br />

vs. replacement (Figure 2). For the<br />

replacement option, the basic question<br />

is whether the replacement motor<br />

should be at the standard efficiency<br />

level in the given market – dictated by a<br />

minimum energy per<strong>for</strong>mance standard<br />

or prevailing practice – or whether to<br />

aim <strong>for</strong> premium efficiency. Availability<br />

is often a limiting factor in this choice,<br />

since plant downtime represents a loss<br />

of income: if high efficiency models are<br />

not stocked by distributors, they are not<br />

an option. Similarly, it is quite common<br />

<strong>for</strong> production facilities to keep reserve<br />

motors in stock, so the baseline is<br />

provided by the efficiency of these<br />

motors.<br />

• New construction would normally involve<br />

the entire motor system. The basic<br />

choice facing an enterprise is to aim <strong>for</strong><br />

business-as-usual (BAU) efficiency as<br />

opposed to a high-efficiency system in<br />

the design and procurement process.<br />

Looking at the additionality question from the<br />

perspective of the end-user highlights the need<br />

to differentiate between the discretionary retrofit,<br />

planned replacement and <strong>new</strong> installation<br />

and construction markets. Some specific<br />

recommendations on additionality provisions<br />

are the following: 20<br />

• Generally exempt end-use efficiency<br />

retrofit projects and programmes from the<br />

requirement to demonstrate additionality,<br />

as a strong argument can be made that<br />

retrofit projects always face additional<br />

cost, financial and related risk barriers,<br />

which the <strong>CDM</strong> (via investment or CER<br />

revenues) can help to overcome.<br />

• Under the SSC rules, it is necessary<br />

to demonstrate at least one barrier<br />

listed in Attachment A to Appendix<br />

B of the simplified modalities and<br />

procedures <strong>for</strong> small-scale <strong>CDM</strong><br />

project activities. Attachment A should<br />

be expanded to include specific<br />

provisions <strong>for</strong> end-use efficiency<br />

projects, such as the following proposal:<br />

“It is recognized that barriers to enduse<br />

energy efficiency are significant and<br />

pervasive. There<strong>for</strong>e, end-use efficiency<br />

project activities that represent discretionary<br />

retrofits to functioning equipment or systems<br />

are considered a priori to be additional. With<br />

respect to planned replacements (at the time<br />

of equipment failure) and <strong>new</strong> installations,<br />

the investment barrier can include a higher<br />

up-front purchase price, even if the project<br />

activity would represent a financially more<br />

viable alternative to the baseline when<br />

accounting <strong>for</strong> savings in energy costs over<br />

the lifetime of the project.”<br />

• The <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board should prepare<br />

with expert input a dedicated tool to<br />

demonstrate the additionality of enduse<br />

efficiency projects or programmes<br />

using barrier analysis <strong>for</strong> integration<br />

into large-scale methodologies. This tool<br />

would have to adopt the basic premise<br />

that barriers to end-use efficiency exist,<br />

as is well documented and evidenced<br />

by the fact that investments in end-use<br />

efficiency are not being made, despite<br />

20 Refer also to submissions at http://cdm.unfccc.int/public_inputs/2008/cers_rev/index.html<br />

140<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


their short payback periods. 21 Such a tool<br />

might include the following elements:<br />

o Checklist of relevant, generic<br />

barriers to end-use energy<br />

efficiency. The Checklist<br />

should include a description<br />

or justification of each barrier,<br />

drawing on the extensive<br />

documentation available in the<br />

published literature. This would<br />

mean that common barriers would<br />

be well-documented or justified<br />

once from the top down and that<br />

each project would then only need<br />

to provide evidence that a barrier<br />

selected from the Checklist applies<br />

in the specific project context<br />

(without having to justify each<br />

time that the barrier is real, which<br />

is a large source of inefficiency<br />

and inconsistency in the current<br />

framework).<br />

o Top-down pre-determination of<br />

additionality, based on barrier<br />

analysis, <strong>for</strong> important large-scale<br />

energy-efficiency programme types<br />

(e.g., utility DSM programmes,<br />

ESCO or leasing schemes, energy<br />

efficiency financing facilities,<br />

government procurement and<br />

municipal infrastructure investment<br />

programes, rebate and financial<br />

incentive programmes, incentives<br />

under voluntary agreements)<br />

or specific guidance on how to<br />

demonstrate the barriers <strong>for</strong><br />

such programmes. Some initial<br />

considerations regarding how<br />

to demonstrate the additionality<br />

of utility DSM programmes have<br />

already been drawn up (Arquit<br />

The <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board should prepare with<br />

expert input a dedicated tool to demonstrate<br />

the additionality of end-use efficiency projects<br />

or programmes using barrier analysis <strong>for</strong><br />

integration into large-scale methodologies. This<br />

tool would have to adopt the basic premise<br />

that barriers to end-use efficiency exist, as is<br />

well documented and evidenced by the fact that<br />

investments in end-use efficiency are not being<br />

made, despite their short payback periods<br />

o<br />

Niederberger and Fry, 2007).<br />

Specific documentation<br />

requirements <strong>for</strong> barrier analysis<br />

of other project types that can<br />

be met without <strong>new</strong> analysis<br />

(e.g., documentation of the use<br />

of government or GEF funds to<br />

provide incentives <strong>for</strong> such types<br />

of projects or programmes in order<br />

to indicate additionality; market<br />

research demonstrating that the<br />

project technology has a higher upfront<br />

capital cost than the baseline<br />

technology; official documents<br />

showing that the technology to<br />

be used in the project activity is<br />

more efficient than a mandatory<br />

standard, voluntary label or other<br />

widely used benchmark level in<br />

order to demonstrate additionality).<br />

21 New results from government-funded audits in hundreds of US<br />

industrial installations have uncovered large energy-saving potential, with<br />

the vast majority having payback periods of less than two years: www.<br />

eere.energy.gov/industry/saveenergynow/partners/results.cfm<br />

Besides the challenge of demonstrating<br />

additionality, the greatest barrier to mobilizing<br />

Scaling Up Energy Efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

141<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


carbon finance <strong>for</strong> end-use efficiency under<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> has been a lack of viable approved<br />

methodologies <strong>for</strong> quantifying energy savings<br />

and emission reductions, as discussed above.<br />

Re<strong>for</strong>m suggestions that draw on experience<br />

with end-use energy efficiency promotion ef<strong>for</strong>ts<br />

worldwide address: (i) the role of the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Executive Board; (ii) the interpretation of key<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> concepts; and (iii) the <strong>new</strong> methodology<br />

development process.<br />

The role of the Executive Board as a regulator<br />

of the <strong>CDM</strong> is crucial. Yet the Board’s role in<br />

providing top-down evaluation guidance is not<br />

well defined. In the case of small-scale projects,<br />

the Board issued an initial series of simplified<br />

methodologies <strong>for</strong> use and has added <strong>new</strong><br />

methodologies over time, based on suggestions<br />

from external stakeholders. In the case of<br />

large-scale methodologies, the Board offers<br />

consolidated methodologies based on individual<br />

methodologies developed by stakeholders,<br />

but does not offer <strong>new</strong> methodologies itself.<br />

Table 3. Description of Selected Cali<strong>for</strong>nia Evaluation Protocols<br />

Protocol<br />

Description<br />

Impact<br />

Evaluation –<br />

Direct and<br />

Indirect<br />

Market Effects<br />

Evaluation<br />

Codes and<br />

Standards<br />

Program<br />

Evaluation<br />

Measurement<br />

and Verification<br />

Sampling and<br />

Uncertainty<br />

Effective Useful<br />

Life<br />

Minimum allowable methods to meet a specified level of rigour that will be used to measure<br />

and document the programme or programme component impacts achieved as a result of<br />

implementing energy efficiency programmes and programme portfolios. Impact evaluations<br />

estimate net changes in electricity usage, electricity demand, therm usage and/or behavioural<br />

impacts that are expected to produce changes in energy use and demand. Impact evaluations<br />

are limited to addressing the direct or indirect energy impacts of the programme on<br />

participants, <strong>including</strong> participant spill-over impacts.<br />

Guidance on evaluations conducted to document the various market changes that affect the<br />

way energy is used within a market and to estimate the energy and demand savings associated<br />

with those changes that are induced by sets of programme or portfolio interventions in a<br />

market.<br />

Designed to guide evaluation approaches to meet the specific needs <strong>for</strong> codes and standards<br />

programmes, <strong>including</strong> net energy impacts associated with a code or standard change.<br />

Requirements <strong>for</strong> field measurements and data collection to support impact evaluations,<br />

updates to ex-ante measure savings estimates (deemed) and process evaluations. Note that<br />

not every evaluation study requires M&V.<br />

Approaches <strong>for</strong> selecting samples and conducting research design and analysis in order to<br />

identify, mitigate and minimize bias in support of the Protocols identified above.<br />

Approaches <strong>for</strong> establishing the effective useful life of programme measures (<strong>including</strong><br />

evaluation of measure retention and technical degradation of measure per<strong>for</strong>mance).<br />

Source: CPUC (2006)<br />

142<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


The Board also issues piecemeal guidance<br />

on individual topics, but has never issued a<br />

comprehensive evaluation protocol that would<br />

provide guidance to project participants, DOEs,<br />

their own panels and UNFCCC secretariat staff.<br />

Particularly in the field of energy efficiency, there is<br />

a wealth of in<strong>for</strong>mation to draw on in establishing<br />

such evaluation frameworks (Arquit Niederberger,<br />

2007). The Cali<strong>for</strong>nia Public Utility Commission,<br />

<strong>for</strong> example, has issued the “Cali<strong>for</strong>nia Energy<br />

Efficiency Evaluation Protocols” (CPUC, 2006),<br />

which includes separate detailed protocols that could<br />

in<strong>for</strong>m the <strong>CDM</strong> regulatory framework (Table 3).<br />

Relying on such protocols as a starting point<br />

also offers some suggestions <strong>for</strong> how to realize<br />

the <strong>new</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> vision presented above. Adopting<br />

and/or updating building codes and minimum<br />

energy per<strong>for</strong>mance standards, <strong>for</strong> example, is<br />

one important action that developing countries<br />

can take to contribute to the ultimate objective<br />

of the Convention, yet the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board<br />

has ruled that such regulatory ef<strong>for</strong>ts are not<br />

eligible under the <strong>CDM</strong>. In contrast, the CPUC<br />

Codes & Standards Protocol offers a methodology<br />

to estimate gross and net energy savings <strong>for</strong> both<br />

(i) programmes that change or contribute to a<br />

change in building codes or appliance standards<br />

that are expected to result in energy savings, and<br />

(ii) programmes that are implemented to increase<br />

the level of compliance with code requirements.<br />

Similarly, the COP/MOP or <strong>CDM</strong> Executive<br />

Board could decide to undertake market<br />

impacts analyses periodically to investigate<br />

whether the <strong>CDM</strong> is only a zero sum game,<br />

making Annex I compliance more costeffective,<br />

or whether <strong>CDM</strong> project activities<br />

are driving broader market trans<strong>for</strong>mation<br />

impacts in host countries that cannot be<br />

evaluated at the level of an individual project.<br />

These protocols also address various crosscutting<br />

issues that are particularly pertinent to<br />

end-use efficiency ef<strong>for</strong>ts (e.g., measurement and<br />

verification requirements; determination of free<br />

ridership and positive spillovers; determination<br />

of standard values <strong>for</strong> parameters such as effective<br />

useful life, deemed energy savings and net-to-gross<br />

of free ridership values) in a consistent, top-down<br />

fashion, which is sorely lacking under the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

However, it is clear that striving to adopt such an<br />

evaluation framework will necessitate changes in<br />

the division of labour between the Parties to the<br />

Kyoto Protocol, the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board (and its<br />

panels), the DOEs, and the project participants.<br />

Another advantage of adopting a more “topdown”<br />

approach would be greater coherence in<br />

the interpretation of key <strong>CDM</strong> concepts (e.g.,<br />

additionality, leakage, treatment of poli cies and<br />

measures in the baseline scenario) by the various<br />

entities active in the carbon mar ket, <strong>including</strong><br />

the panels and working groups appointed by the<br />

Executive Board.<br />

Finally, it is necessary to consider the best<br />

way <strong>for</strong>ward in developing <strong>new</strong> quantification<br />

methodologies <strong>for</strong> end-use efficiency projects. The<br />

results of the vast ef<strong>for</strong>ts that have been invested<br />

in methodology development are meagre, with<br />

only a total of eighteen energy-demand (sectoral<br />

scope 3) projects having been registered to date<br />

(Table 2). The majority of the approved energydemand<br />

methodologies have never been used,<br />

and the small-scale Type II end-use efficiency<br />

methodologies have prove difficult to apply in<br />

practice, as they provide too little guidance. It is<br />

time to take stock and conclude that the bottom up<br />

approach has not worked – and is not desirable –<br />

<strong>for</strong> end-use energy efficiency, and that a common<br />

methodological framework <strong>for</strong> energy efficiency<br />

quantification is needed. The development of<br />

Scaling Up Energy Efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

143<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


such a framework should draw on the vast expertise<br />

within the energy efficiency community, <strong>for</strong><br />

example, by adopting energy savings quantification<br />

“good practice” as codified in existing protocols,<br />

adapted as necessary to meet the requirements of<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong>. This should be treated as a priority of<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board, but coordinated with<br />

the broader ef<strong>for</strong>t of developing methodological<br />

guidance on quantification and reporting on the<br />

effects of measures, which is currently negotiated<br />

under the AWG-LCA. COP14 should initiate the<br />

process of developing consistent guidance.<br />

The desire to monitor, quantify and attribute the<br />

impacts of individual <strong>CDM</strong> projects precisely<br />

and accurately will be increasingly futile, given<br />

the range of regulatory, institutional, technology,<br />

financial and capacity development ef<strong>for</strong>ts that<br />

will be required. This is particularly true in the<br />

context of climate mitigation, which must deliver<br />

trans<strong>for</strong>ma tional emission cuts globally within<br />

decades. The <strong>CDM</strong> should be regarded as a risk/<br />

reward incentive mechanism to stimulate greater<br />

investment in climate mitigation and sustainable<br />

development, not as an accounting tool <strong>for</strong><br />

perfect offsetting.<br />

Conclusion<br />

The Clean Development Mechanism has proved<br />

ineffective in stimulating investment in end-use<br />

energy efficiency. This will come as no surprise to<br />

energy efficiency practitioners, who understand<br />

that large-scale market trans<strong>for</strong>mation requires<br />

a multi-pronged approach, but it is nonetheless<br />

a disappointment to many developing countries<br />

that could benefit greatly from <strong>CDM</strong> funding<br />

<strong>for</strong> large-scale energy efficiency programs to<br />

distribute efficient end-use equipment, <strong>for</strong><br />

example, or implement green building codes and<br />

minimum energy-per<strong>for</strong>mance standards.<br />

Dr Anne Arquit Niederberger has extensive experience in the<br />

field of climate change research, energy policy, capacity building<br />

and strategic consulting, with a current emphasis on China. She has<br />

special expertise on end-use efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong>, and is a<br />

founding director of Policy Solutions, an independent consultancy.<br />

Contact: policy.solutions@comcast.net<br />

Fortunately, the Bali Roadmap process presents us<br />

with a brief window of opportunity to ensure that<br />

the climate deal to be brokered in Copenhagen<br />

in December 2009 provides the foundation <strong>for</strong> a<br />

global energy-efficiency offensive, with the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

as one tool. But there is a lot of work to be done<br />

to anchor the vision presented in this paper in the<br />

post-2012 framework.<br />

For the <strong>CDM</strong> to achieve its dual mitigation<br />

and sustainable development objectives, the<br />

Parties can no longer be satisfied with perfect<br />

environmental integrity of a zero-sum <strong>CDM</strong> at<br />

the expense of real action on end-use efficiency.<br />

144<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


References<br />

Arquit Niederberger, A., Advancing Energy Efficiency Under the Bali Action<br />

Plan. UNFCCC submission in response to the call <strong>for</strong> input from accredited<br />

observer organizations included in FCCC/AWGLCA/2008/L.7,<br />

September 2008.<br />

Arquit Niederberger, A., Energy Efficiency Projects in <strong>CDM</strong>. Seminar Issue<br />

Paper, UNIDO/CTI/UK Trade & Investment Seminar on Energy Efficiency<br />

Projects in <strong>CDM</strong> and JI, Vienna, 19-20 March 2007.<br />

Arquit Niederberger, A., MDG Carbon Finance Action Plans: Leveraging<br />

New Markets <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development, <strong>CDM</strong> Investment Newsletter,<br />

1/2006, 3-6, 2006.<br />

Arquit Niederberger, A., and C. Brunner, Promotion of High-Efficiency<br />

Electric Motor Systems Under the Clean Development Mechanism, Conference<br />

Proceedings, 5th International Conference on Energy Efficiency in<br />

Motor Driven Systems. Beijing, 2007.<br />

Arquit Niederberger, A., and T. Fry, An Eye on Demand, Environmental<br />

Finance, Special Supplement, S52, November 2007.<br />

Arquit Niederberger, A., and R. Spalding-Fecher, Demand-side energy<br />

efficiency promotion under the Clean Development Mechanism: lessons<br />

learned and future prospects, Energy <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development, X(4),<br />

45-58, December 2006.<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>-EB, Report of the Thirty-Second Meeting of the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board,<br />

Annex 6. <strong>CDM</strong>-EB-32, 22 June 2007.<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>-EB, Report of the Twenty-Second Meeting of the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board,<br />

Annex 3. <strong>CDM</strong>-EB-22, 25 November 2005.<br />

CPUC, Cali<strong>for</strong>nia Energy Efficiency Evaluation Protocols: Technical, Methodological,<br />

and Reporting Requirements <strong>for</strong> Evaluation Professionals. Cali<strong>for</strong>nia<br />

Public Utility Commission, April 2006.<br />

EGEE, Realizing the Potential of Energy Efficiency – Targets, Policies and<br />

Measures <strong>for</strong> G8 Countries. United Nations Foundation, Washington, July<br />

2007.<br />

GOC, China’s National Climate Change Programme. National Development<br />

and Re<strong>for</strong>m Commission, Government of China, 3 June 2008, 62 pp.<br />

GOI, National Action Plan on Climate Change. Prime Minister’s Council on<br />

Climate Change, Government of India, 30 June 2008, 49 pp.<br />

Hinostroza, M., Cheng, C.-C., Zhu, X., Fenhann, J., Figueres, C., and F.<br />

Avendaño, Potentials and Barriers <strong>for</strong> End-Use Energy Efficiency under<br />

Programmatic <strong>CDM</strong>, UNEP Riso CD4<strong>CDM</strong> Working Paper Series, 3, September<br />

2007.<br />

IEA, Energy Efficiency Policy Recommendations. Paris: International Energy<br />

Agency, 2008.<br />

IIEC, Final Evaluation of CFL Program (Phases 1& 2). Report prepared by<br />

the International Institute <strong>for</strong> Energy Conservation (IIEC) – Asia <strong>for</strong> Electricity<br />

of Vietnam in the context of the Vietnam Demand Side Management<br />

and Energy Efficiency (DSM/EE) Project, April 2007.<br />

Reddy, B.S., and P. Balachandra, Climate change mitigation and business<br />

opportunities: the case of the household sector in India, Energy <strong>for</strong> Sustainable<br />

Development, X(4), 59-73, December 2006.<br />

Shukla, P.R., Climate Change Divide, Sakaal Times ePaper, 6 August 2008.<br />

Takada, M. and S. Fracchia, A Review of Energy in National MDG Reports.<br />

UN Development Program, January 2007.<br />

UNEP Risø <strong>CDM</strong> Pipeline, 1 September 2008<br />

Scaling Up Energy Efficiency under the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

145<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


146<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Murray Ward<br />

Principal of the Global<br />

Climate Change Consultancy<br />

Sector No-Lose Targets:<br />

A New Scaling Up Mechanism<br />

For Developing Countries<br />

Abstract<br />

Sector no-lose targets (SNLTs) are a promising<br />

<strong>new</strong> carbon-market mechanism <strong>for</strong> scaling up<br />

investment in low-carbon technology in developing<br />

countries. A key characteristic of SNLTs is that,<br />

because they would be negotiated as part of the<br />

multilateral agreement along with industrialised<br />

countries’ targets, the concept of additionality<br />

would not apply, nor would any of the institutional<br />

processes of the <strong>CDM</strong>. Countries would need<br />

to have well-developed national monitoring,<br />

reporting and verification (MRV) and systems at<br />

the sector level. SNLTs are not a scaling up silver<br />

bullet, but they have some characteristics which<br />

suggest that, <strong>for</strong> some sectors in key developing<br />

countries where large investments are expected<br />

in the coming decades, they may be the best <strong>new</strong><br />

carbon-finance mechanism identified thus far.<br />

Whether expressed in gigatonnes of needed<br />

emission reductions or tens to hundreds of<br />

gigadollars of needed investment in climate<br />

change mitigation activities worldwide, the<br />

case <strong>for</strong> “scaling up” has been made by world<br />

scientific, political and business leaders. The<br />

task of policy-makers working on the next post-<br />

2012 multilateral agreement is to respond to this<br />

challenge and consider seriously every policy<br />

instrument that may need to be part of the toolkit<br />

to give the global community a reasonable chance<br />

of success. Just making tuning adjustments to the<br />

instruments we have now is not nearly enough.<br />

Sector no-lose targets (SNLTs) <strong>for</strong> developing<br />

countries is one such <strong>new</strong> mechanism. It is a<br />

crediting mechanism that can be applied at<br />

the sectoral level, at least <strong>for</strong> some sectors and<br />

countries. It has the potential to make it much<br />

easier to mobilise the necessary inward investment<br />

and also to help strike a balance between the<br />

interests of developed and industrialised country<br />

parties to such investment.<br />

147<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


However, SNLTs come with some unique<br />

challenges, <strong>for</strong> example: data needs to establish<br />

sector baselines at a national level; MRV capacity<br />

needs; understanding the effects on international<br />

competitiveness; institutional process and timing<br />

issues; and ensuring carbon market engagement<br />

and momentum. Overcoming even the initial<br />

set of these will require very substantial and<br />

deliberate capacity-building and international<br />

diplomacy ef<strong>for</strong>ts if countries are ever to be<br />

prepared to reach such agreements in the post-<br />

2012 multilateral package.<br />

These issues and challenges are set out and<br />

discussed below. This is done with a view to<br />

giving negotiators a sense of priority next steps<br />

to programme into work streams leading to<br />

Copenhagen.<br />

Background<br />

This <strong>new</strong> proposed mechanism of SNLTs can be<br />

seen to have emerged from two different strands of<br />

policy work. The first is the exploration in various<br />

<strong>for</strong>ums of <strong>new</strong> potential types of enhanced policy<br />

tools that might be applicable <strong>for</strong> developing<br />

countries in a post-2012 agreement.<br />

In particular, the Future Actions Dialogue run by<br />

the Centre <strong>for</strong> Clean Air Policy (CCAP) since<br />

2003 came to a view after a few years that<br />

sectoral mechanisms held out the greatest<br />

promise, especially if they were framed in<br />

intensity terms. This is because economy-wide<br />

targets, even intensity-based ones, seem to go<br />

beyond the realms of reasonable expectation<br />

in this next phase of global climate change<br />

agreements. Moreover, economy-wide targets<br />

can have practical structural difficulties such<br />

as the double pain problem, where targets are<br />

expressed in emissions per GDP. 1 But intensitybased<br />

sectoral mechanisms would not suffer this<br />

problem.<br />

In addition to the CCAP work, there has been<br />

considerable analytical ef<strong>for</strong>t done on sectoral<br />

crediting mechanisms by the Annex I Experts<br />

Group, supported by its secretariat experts at<br />

the OECD and the International Energy Agency<br />

(IEA) (e.g. see Baron et al., 2007; Baron and Ellis,<br />

2006; Ellis and Baron, 2005).<br />

The second strand has come out of the high-level<br />

work on scaling up investments in low-carbon<br />

technologies, which has mostly been led by the<br />

G8 Gleneagles Dialogue process, also involving<br />

the World Bank and IEA. Recent papers <strong>for</strong> UK<br />

DEFRA (Ward et al., 2008) and the World Bank<br />

Carbon Finance Unit (Ward, Garibaldi et al.,<br />

2008) pull these two strands together, as well as<br />

placing SNLTs in the broader context of other<br />

scaling up mechanisms, such as programmatic<br />

and sectoral <strong>CDM</strong>, and other sectoral policy<br />

approaches <strong>for</strong> developing countries, such as SD<br />

PAMs.<br />

Papers (Colombier and Guerin, 2008 and Ward,<br />

2008) from the recent Tony Blair and Climate<br />

Group Breaking the Climate Deadlock initiative<br />

have also sought to place sectoral crediting<br />

mechanisms such as SNLTs within the broader<br />

spectrum of sectoral approaches, <strong>including</strong> sectoral<br />

agreements that can bridge industrialised and<br />

developing countries.<br />

This paper draws on this earlier body of work and<br />

seeks to summarise and distil some key messages<br />

about SNLTs in particular.<br />

1 Here, countries could find themselves struggling to meet targets<br />

if their GDP fell (e.g. <strong>for</strong> macroeconomic and global commodity price<br />

reasons) without a commensurate drop in domestic emissions.<br />

148<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


The SNLT policy tool<br />

SNLTs are a <strong>for</strong>m of non-binding emission target<br />

that could encourage sector-wide emission<br />

reductions. Developing countries could<br />

voluntarily propose a sector crediting baseline<br />

which would be negotiated at the international<br />

level, most likely in terms of the national<br />

emissions intensity of the sector in question over<br />

a commitment or management period of time.<br />

Reductions below the baseline generate credits<br />

issued to the government, but no penalties would<br />

occur (hence “no lose”) if the target is not met <strong>for</strong><br />

the whole sector. See Figure 1.<br />

What is depicted in Figure 1 could also describe<br />

what has been called “sectoral <strong>CDM</strong>” where some<br />

<strong>for</strong>m of baseline is established <strong>for</strong> a sector e.g. a<br />

multi-project baseline or benchmark and credits<br />

are awarded <strong>for</strong> beating this baseline. The main<br />

difference between sectoral <strong>CDM</strong> and SNLTs<br />

is that the technicalities referring to baselines,<br />

monitoring and verification, as well as supervision<br />

and approval by the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board, would<br />

be maintained under sectoral <strong>CDM</strong>. Proponents<br />

of the SNLT mechanism propose that the national<br />

sector baseline <strong>for</strong> a SNLT would instead be<br />

negotiated at the COP level. This would be done<br />

as part of the same negotiating process in which<br />

Annex I country targets <strong>for</strong> post-2012 are being<br />

agreed, so additionality would no longer be an<br />

issue, any more than it is <strong>for</strong> actions taken by<br />

Annex I countries that have targets.<br />

This additionality distinction between SNLTs and<br />

any <strong>for</strong>m of <strong>CDM</strong> is what distinguishes this policy<br />

Figure 1: Simple depiction of a sectoral crediting baseline<br />

Source Ecofys/GtripleC (2006)<br />

A New Scaling Up Mechanism For Developing Countries<br />

149<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


tool in particular, suggesting that it might have the<br />

greatest potential <strong>for</strong> scaling up investments, at<br />

least in appropriate sectors. The single main reason<br />

<strong>for</strong> constraints in the <strong>CDM</strong> is the institutional<br />

decision-making processes associated with additionality<br />

and environmental integrity.<br />

As noted above, the idea <strong>for</strong> SNLTs stems from<br />

discussions occurring as far back as 2003 in the<br />

CCAP Future Actions Dialogue. Two variants of this<br />

idea have now emerged, largely independently<br />

of each other. Of the two, the CCAP approach<br />

(see Schmidt et al, 2006) can be seen as a more<br />

prescriptive version and one with elements<br />

that are specifically intended to address international<br />

competitiveness concerns. The CCAP<br />

approach would focus on the ten largest<br />

developing-country emitters <strong>for</strong> each of the<br />

major sectors proposed e.g. electricity, iron and<br />

steel, chemical and petrochemical, aluminium,<br />

cement and limestone, paper pulp and printing.<br />

A technology and financing package would<br />

be provided to these countries to offset the<br />

costs of their involvement. These costs stem<br />

from the requirement <strong>for</strong> crediting baselines<br />

to incorporate a non-crediting element that<br />

represents these countries’ contribution to<br />

the atmosphere. The competitiveness-focused<br />

elements relate to the use of pre-set benchmarks<br />

established by third-party independent-expert<br />

bodies. These benchmarks provide the starting<br />

point <strong>for</strong> negotiations with developing countries<br />

on what their specific crediting baselines should<br />

be. The benchmarks are also intended to guide<br />

allocations <strong>for</strong> industries in these sectors<br />

operating in the EU ETS, and presumably other<br />

industrialised countries as well.<br />

The other variant of the SNLT idea, developed<br />

by GtripleC and Ecofys, has centred on the<br />

development of sectoral proposal templates (see<br />

www.sectoral.org). The purpose of these templates<br />

– which could be used by any developing country<br />

seeking to propose such a target voluntarily<br />

as part of the post-2012 negotiations – is to<br />

provide a standardised tool by which countries<br />

can draw up and propose crediting baselines.<br />

These templates are initially seen as a capacitybuilding<br />

tool <strong>for</strong> countries to use internally. In<br />

turn, they become a negotiation facilitation tool<br />

to help the process of negotiations by providing<br />

some level of standardisation of in<strong>for</strong>mation,<br />

presentation and transparency. The templates<br />

include details of best practice as this exists in<br />

other countries, not with a view to these being<br />

seen as benchmarks and used as the basis <strong>for</strong><br />

negotiations. And instead of the notion of having<br />

a negotiated technology and finance package, the<br />

templates describe what internationally provided<br />

support countries may be receiving in a given<br />

sector (or might receive in the future) that can<br />

allow them to achieve lower emissions separate<br />

from the support of carbon finance.<br />

These summary differences aside, both concepts<br />

share the characteristics of voluntarily proposed<br />

targets being intended <strong>for</strong> developing countries.<br />

The metric <strong>for</strong> these targets will most likely be set<br />

in intensity terms, e.g. tonnes CO 2<br />

per tonne of<br />

cement or per MWh electricity. This distinguishes<br />

these concepts from so-called ‘transnational<br />

sectoral targets’, i.e. industry sectoral targets,<br />

where the aim would be targets (or benchmarks)<br />

<strong>for</strong> industries operating in both industrialised<br />

and developing countries.<br />

While the CCAP proposal does have an element<br />

of this competitiveness-focused thinking in its<br />

use of international benchmarks, as it applies<br />

to developing countries, it is clearly in the same<br />

family of ideas as the GtripleC/Ecofys variant. In<br />

particular, where this paper focuses on domestic<br />

implementation issues, these should generally<br />

apply to either variant of the concept.<br />

150<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


SNLT candidate sectors<br />

It can be expected that developing countries may<br />

be stimulated to consider SNLTs in sectors <strong>for</strong><br />

which they seek significantly scaled-up privatesector<br />

investment according to their sustainable<br />

development priorities, and where current<br />

carbon-market policy tools, such as the various<br />

<strong>for</strong>ms of <strong>CDM</strong>, are not considered adequate to<br />

the task.<br />

However, SNLTs are unlikely to be feasible <strong>for</strong><br />

all key sectors, and even <strong>for</strong> those sectors where<br />

they may be feasible, this may not be true in<br />

all developing countries. Like all credit-based<br />

mechanisms, it is necessary with SNLTs to<br />

establish a baseline, and then measure, report<br />

and verify per<strong>for</strong>mance against this.<br />

The metric of this baseline, then, must be<br />

something that is measurable in practice and<br />

where a measured change is representative<br />

of either reduced tonnes of emissions to the<br />

atmosphere, or enhanced sequestration. This<br />

becomes increasingly challenging as one moves<br />

away from project-scale <strong>CDM</strong> projects towards<br />

something at the sector level. Moreover, given<br />

that the the SNLT tool is used in developing<br />

countries, the per<strong>for</strong>mance metric is typically<br />

framed in intensity 2 terms to ensure that it does<br />

not operate as a cap on development. Having<br />

intensity baselines also means the need <strong>for</strong> the<br />

parameter that is the denominator in the metric<br />

to be measurable and, in turn, measured, reported<br />

and verified.<br />

Some examples of possible sectors and baseline<br />

metrics are:<br />

2 At the end of a given management period, when the per<strong>for</strong>mance of<br />

the denominator parameter is known, intensity targets can be converted<br />

into absolute tonnes and compared with tonnes of emissions, thus enabling<br />

credits to be issued in ‘tonnes’.<br />

• electricity generation: tonnes CO e per 2<br />

MWh generated. Note also that this would<br />

represent tonnes of emissions emitted<br />

into the atmosphere, so reductions<br />

from carbon capture and storage (CCS)<br />

would be picked up under this metric. It<br />

might also be feasible to do a separate<br />

sector baseline <strong>for</strong> resultant emissions<br />

associated with electricity losses in<br />

transmission and distribution systems.<br />

Sectoral no-lose targets (SNLTs) are<br />

particularly appropriate <strong>for</strong> rapidly<br />

industrialising (or developing) countries<br />

where there is a need <strong>for</strong> significant capital<br />

investment, and where investments are<br />

otherwise likely to follow historical high-carbon<br />

patterns typical of industrialised countries.<br />

• cement, aluminium or steel production:<br />

tonnes CO 2<br />

e per tonne produced. Some<br />

similar industrial commodities may also<br />

be feasible, e.g. bricks, pulp and paper,<br />

some chemicals, <strong>including</strong> refined oil<br />

products, and some mining and mineral<br />

processing.<br />

• upstream emissions of oil and gas production<br />

(e.g. gas flaring): tonnes CO 2<br />

e<br />

per barrel of oil delivered to refineries<br />

or export facilities, or volume of gas<br />

delivered.<br />

Notably, most of these examples are industrial<br />

in nature and probably reflect smaller numbers<br />

of large sources. By comparison, sectors such<br />

as buildings and transport have large numbers<br />

of small sources. A SNLT approach here is<br />

A New Scaling Up Mechanism For Developing Countries<br />

151<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


much more complex and perhaps not feasible –<br />

although it may be possible to define some subsectors,<br />

<strong>including</strong> perhaps regions of sub-sectors<br />

that are sub-national in scale.<br />

SNLT candidate countries<br />

As discussed above, the CCAP variant of SNLTs<br />

proposes a focus on the top ten emitters among<br />

developing countries <strong>for</strong> given key sectors. In<br />

contrast, the Ecofys/GtripleC approach takes<br />

the perspective that SNLTs should be open to any<br />

developing country that wishes to propose SNLTs<br />

voluntarily and that can develop the requisite<br />

measurement, reporting and verification (MRV)<br />

national systems capacities.<br />

More generally, the key issue is scaling up the<br />

investment in low-carbon technology in key<br />

investments, especially in <strong>new</strong> infrastructure<br />

investments, but also in upgrades of existing<br />

capital stock. This suggests that SNLTs are<br />

particularly appropriate <strong>for</strong> rapidly industrialising<br />

(or developing) countries where there is a need<br />

<strong>for</strong> significant capital investment, and where<br />

investments are otherwise likely to follow historical<br />

high-carbon patterns typical of industrialised<br />

countries. The Energy Investments Outlook work<br />

of the IEA provides a useful in<strong>for</strong>mation base<br />

that describes in which countries such major<br />

investments in low-carbon technology are likely to<br />

be needed.<br />

In some cases, the nature of the sector provides<br />

insights into which countries might benefit most.<br />

So, <strong>for</strong> example, an SNLT <strong>for</strong> upstream oil and<br />

gas processing focusing especially on gas flaring<br />

may be particularly relevant to countries such<br />

as Indonesia and Nigeria. Similarly, an SNLT <strong>for</strong><br />

electricity transmission and distribution may be<br />

particularly relevant to India.<br />

Finally, there is a big picture politics to this.<br />

Section 9 below takes up the issue of the need of<br />

a demand <strong>for</strong> the scaled up supply of credits that<br />

SNLTs imply. This demand will only come from<br />

the much deeper absolute and economy-wide<br />

emission-reduction targets that are expected<br />

of industrialised countries in the post-2012<br />

agreement. However, <strong>for</strong> these countries to take<br />

on and ratify such targets, it is likely that there<br />

is a strong domestic political need <strong>for</strong> major<br />

developing countries to take on targets of some<br />

type too, especially in some key sectors such as<br />

electricity generation.<br />

Fit with other policy tools<br />

SNLTs can be seen as one of a menu of possible<br />

international policy tools <strong>for</strong> developing<br />

countries that provide some kind of incentive. As<br />

noted above, SNLTs are seen as being potentially<br />

applicable to some key sectors in some developing<br />

countries. Other carbon-finance policy tools<br />

include the family of possible variants of the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> mechanism (standard project-based,<br />

programmatic, policy-based, sectoral). Noncarbon<br />

finance policies include, <strong>for</strong> example, SD-<br />

PAMs and specific sectoral agreements, with <strong>for</strong><br />

both of these some <strong>for</strong>m of technology and/or<br />

financial support.<br />

In general, if a country implements an SNLT in<br />

a given sector, this sector is no longer eligible<br />

<strong>for</strong> <strong>new</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> activities, as this would potentially<br />

lead to double crediting. However, a <strong>for</strong>m of JIlike<br />

mechanism could be employed domestically<br />

to nest project-based carbon financing within<br />

such a sector. This is taken up below in section<br />

8.<br />

Conceptually, there is no problem in having a<br />

mix of an SNLT and SD-PAMs and other <strong>for</strong>ms<br />

of non-carbon finance policies occurring in the<br />

152<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


same sector. These other policies can be seen as<br />

being part of the discussions about the baseline<br />

beyond which carbon finance under an SNLT<br />

applies. This is depicted below in Figure 2 in<br />

section 7.<br />

Major steps to include SNLTs in<br />

the post-2012 agreement<br />

High-level issues<br />

A series of steps are needed at both the national<br />

level of interested developing countries and the<br />

international intergovernmental level. In the<br />

interests of time, and given that this <strong>new</strong> policy<br />

tool is being proposed as potentially a key <strong>new</strong><br />

mechanism in the post-2012 period, it will be<br />

important that the national and international<br />

steps proceed in parallel – and expeditiously!<br />

It is important not to impose a set of expectations<br />

on developing countries beyond what is<br />

expected of industrialised countries, especially<br />

where infringements on sovereign rights and<br />

responsibilities may be perceived. SNLTs need<br />

to be seen in the context of targets voluntarily<br />

taken on in a multilateral negotiation process, as<br />

distinct from baselines of the <strong>CDM</strong> type. To this<br />

extent, SNLTs are not unlike the targets that will<br />

be taken on by industrialised countries, although<br />

there are some key technical differences. 3 But in<br />

both cases, the beating of a target has the result<br />

of creating tradable emission units called credits<br />

in the case of SNLTs, and Assigned Amount Units<br />

(AAUs) in the case of industrialised country<br />

targets. In either case, <strong>for</strong> example, excessively<br />

soft targets have the potential to be a source<br />

of excessive supply to the carbon market and<br />

undermine its effectiveness <strong>for</strong> all countries.<br />

3 In particular, SNLTs are expected to be defined in intensity terms,<br />

meaning that credits are issued ex-post following verified per<strong>for</strong>mance<br />

over a given period.<br />

Any differences in the treatment of prospective<br />

targets <strong>for</strong> industrialised countries and SNLTs<br />

<strong>for</strong> developing countries there<strong>for</strong>e need to be<br />

grounded in an objective realisation of facts.<br />

A key issue here is the different capacities<br />

and capabilities relating to MRV systems.<br />

Industrialised countries have had nearly ten<br />

years to prepare <strong>for</strong> the Kyoto Protocol’s first<br />

commitment period, whereas <strong>for</strong> developing<br />

countries MRV has mostly just been focused<br />

at the project level, when <strong>CDM</strong> activities were<br />

undertaken.<br />

One issue that seems to need the serious<br />

and immediate attention of the international<br />

community is how the post-2012 negotiations<br />

are going to cope with the need <strong>for</strong> objective and<br />

accurate data and analysis of countries’ national<br />

circumstances, <strong>including</strong> proposals that are<br />

transparent and accessible to all key players in<br />

the negotiations. Significant targeted capacitybuilding<br />

is likely to be needed.<br />

A key characteristic of SNLTs is that,<br />

because they would be negotiated as part<br />

of the multilateral agreement along with<br />

industrialised countries’ targets, the concept<br />

of additionality would not apply, nor would<br />

any of the institutional processes of the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

Under the <strong>CDM</strong>, the Conference of the Parties<br />

(COP) delegated the responsibility <strong>for</strong> accepting<br />

baselines to the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board (EB).<br />

In turn, the EB relies heavily on the technical<br />

expertise it can draw on from its various panels and<br />

working groups. Also, the accredited designated<br />

operational entities (DOEs) have a critical role<br />

to play in the overall quality assurance of EB<br />

A New Scaling Up Mechanism For Developing Countries<br />

153<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


decisions about baselines. Another key point is<br />

that, in the <strong>CDM</strong>, possible errors in judgement<br />

are contained at the project scale.<br />

Agreeing SNLT baselines at the COP level is<br />

a much more significant step. This raises key<br />

institutional questions with respect to the<br />

process of how Parties reach the necessary level<br />

of confidence in their understanding of the<br />

consequences of their impending decisions to<br />

be able to reach final agreements. It seems that<br />

there is a need <strong>for</strong> an objective technical advisory<br />

group to assist the negotiation process of SNLTs,<br />

and perhaps even of industrialised countries’<br />

targets. Its advice should be transparent and<br />

available to all Parties.<br />

The COP may also see the value of establishing<br />

some kind of executive board or group to<br />

manage this technical process and bring<br />

recommendations to the COP. In some ways,<br />

such an executive group would play a similar role<br />

to the <strong>CDM</strong> EB. However, this group would have<br />

a purpose-specific and time-limited function.<br />

And on the issue of time, it would need to be<br />

established very quickly and efficiently, e.g. in<br />

the first half of 2009. Un<strong>for</strong>tunately, the history<br />

of the UNFCCC being able to create such an<br />

institutional group very quickly and efficiently<br />

does not inspire much confidence. But the<br />

UNFCCC process itself needs to be ready to<br />

up its game in order to manage the challenges<br />

presented by the post-2012 negotiations.<br />

National level steps<br />

A first step to generate national interest and<br />

begin the preparation of in<strong>for</strong>mation and data is<br />

to raise awareness of the existence of the SNLTs<br />

policy tool at the national level. This should<br />

be done at various levels of the government,<br />

and also within the industry in a given sector<br />

(or sectors) of a given country that might be<br />

suitable <strong>for</strong> this approach. Initiatives have to<br />

be taken to in<strong>for</strong>m stakeholders by, <strong>for</strong> example,<br />

organising workshops around the subject so that<br />

institutions can take ownership of the technical<br />

exercises that will come.<br />

Once the basics of the approach have been<br />

understood, it will become clearer whether general<br />

interest exists and an initial understanding of the<br />

capacities in a given country can be acquired.<br />

In thinking about their scaling-up priorities,<br />

developing countries will need to decide which<br />

sectors or technologies are most effectively<br />

addressed by a SNLT, and which sectors might<br />

be more effectively dealt with by, <strong>for</strong> example,<br />

programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> or other funding mechanisms.<br />

These are issues which, by their nature, fit well<br />

under the concept of developing countries taking<br />

a strategic programme approach to securing lowcarbon<br />

investment.<br />

Within this initial familiarisation process, an<br />

assessment should be made of which sectors in<br />

a given country might be relevant <strong>for</strong> SNLTs. As<br />

noted in section 4, a key consideration is likely to<br />

be sectors that have large and growing emissions,<br />

where there is a need <strong>for</strong> significant investment<br />

in low-carbon technologies and where such<br />

decisions have significant long-term emission<br />

consequences. These investments might be<br />

either <strong>for</strong> the modernisation of existing or <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>new</strong> infrastructure and plant. It is also likely to<br />

depend on the maturity of the sector, which in<br />

turn depends on data availability and capacities,<br />

among other factors.<br />

For given sectors, countries then need to begin<br />

the process of determining what an appropriate<br />

baseline might be <strong>for</strong> the SNLT. Ecofys/GtripleC’s<br />

work on sectoral proposal templates, noted in<br />

section 3, is specifically intended to help at this<br />

stage. The templates assist a country to prepare<br />

154<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Figure 2: Development of SNLTs<br />

Source: Ward et al, 2008<br />

and, in turn, tell its story in terms of the potential<br />

<strong>for</strong> improvements in GHG intensity <strong>for</strong> the given<br />

sector, following the steps depicted below in<br />

Figure 2.<br />

The in-country ef<strong>for</strong>ts described above in this<br />

section involve a significant commitment of<br />

resources and time. A financing package is likely<br />

to be needed <strong>for</strong> many developing countries to<br />

undertake the necessary in-county work to get<br />

them to the point of being ready to present<br />

proposals <strong>for</strong> SNLTs in the negotiations of the<br />

multilateral post-2012 climate agreement.<br />

Issues arising <strong>for</strong> the negotiation process<br />

Multilateral negotiations by their nature reflect<br />

the interests of all countries, both in broad<br />

groups and individually. Negotiations under<br />

the UNFCCC in particular also reflect a general<br />

consensus-based process. Taking up a <strong>new</strong><br />

mechanism such as SNLTs there<strong>for</strong>e requires a<br />

general consensus that this is useful to achieving<br />

an overall agreement.<br />

The key feature of SNLTs is that they move<br />

beyond the institutional constraints that will<br />

exist <strong>for</strong> any carbon market mechanism where<br />

additionality is a core requirement. Moreover, <strong>for</strong><br />

such sectors and countries, it shifts the focus of<br />

climate-change mitigation to a sector level and<br />

requires management across whole sectors, not<br />

just individual projects or activities.<br />

The potential benefit of scaled-up, carbon marketfinanced<br />

investment <strong>for</strong> developing countries<br />

seems clear. A crucial question is whether<br />

industrialised countries feel that the increased<br />

scope <strong>for</strong> least-cost mitigation, plus mitigation<br />

management at the sector level by developing<br />

countries, provides what they are expecting of<br />

such sectors in developing countries in the post-<br />

2012 regime.<br />

A key underlying issue here is the international<br />

competitiveness of emissions-intensive sectors in<br />

industrialised countries – specifically carbon<br />

leakage. Between industrialised countries this<br />

A New Scaling Up Mechanism For Developing Countries<br />

155<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


concern mostly is displayed through an expectation<br />

that all industrialised countries will take fixed and<br />

binding economy-wide targets. The debate is,<br />

then, how stringent the reduction targets of<br />

individual countries should be. Of course, within<br />

industrialised countries there will be domestic<br />

policy debates about how such national targets<br />

are then distributed among specific sectors,<br />

especially those perceived to be internationally<br />

competitiveness-at-risk. But this is largely a<br />

domestic policy matter that need not be addressed<br />

by the international community.<br />

With respect to SNLTs <strong>for</strong> developing countries,<br />

the <strong>for</strong>m the competitiveness issue takes is<br />

different. It becomes a question of whether<br />

industrialised countries, under pressure from<br />

their domestic industry constituencies, have<br />

specific technical requirements <strong>for</strong> such SNLTs.<br />

These, <strong>for</strong> example, may indicate an expectation<br />

that some sectors in some countries should<br />

be covered in such a regime, or that certain<br />

technical benchmarks should be applied in the<br />

determination of appropriate baselines. This<br />

can be seen as lying behind the CCAP sectors<br />

and top ten-country proposals and their use of<br />

agreed international benchmarks as the starting<br />

point <strong>for</strong> the negotiation of SNLTs.<br />

It is clear that there is traction in some emissionsintensive<br />

industry sectors in industrialised<br />

countries that such competitiveness concerns<br />

should be given serious consideration in any<br />

<strong>for</strong>mulation of a <strong>new</strong> SNLTs mechanism, or <strong>for</strong><br />

that matter, in the <strong>for</strong>mulation of any developing<br />

country commitment. Indeed, there is a view in<br />

some quarters that global industry agreements in<br />

certain competitiveness-prone sectors, such as<br />

cement, iron and steel and aluminium, covering<br />

both industrialised and developing countries<br />

are preferable to having these sectors covered by<br />

SNLTs in developing countries. What is less clear<br />

is whether these competitiveness concerns have<br />

sufficient traction with enough industrialised<br />

country governments <strong>for</strong> this to have an impact<br />

on the development of negotiation modalities<br />

<strong>for</strong> SNLTs.<br />

In addition to competitiveness concerns, there<br />

may be concerns about the scale of credits that<br />

may flow from some sectors if sectoral crediting<br />

were allowed. This issue concerns the potential<br />

mismatch of demand and supply in the carbon<br />

market (i.e. potentially too little demand and too<br />

much supply).<br />

If these competitiveness and potential (oversupply<br />

concerns become sufficiently important<br />

to major players in the negotiations, then the<br />

following type of decision might be deemed<br />

necessary with respect to the development and<br />

negotiation of proposals <strong>for</strong> SNLTs:<br />

• which sectors are suitable on the national<br />

and international level (and which are<br />

not), <strong>including</strong> the technical or other<br />

criteria by which these judgements<br />

might be made<br />

• the demarcations of the sectors in<br />

order to provide <strong>for</strong> international<br />

comparability; while <strong>for</strong> some sectors<br />

boundaries are relatively easy to define<br />

(e.g. the cement sector), this might<br />

be more challenging <strong>for</strong> others (e.g.<br />

chemical production). Spill-over effects<br />

have to be accounted <strong>for</strong>.<br />

• what data and in<strong>for</strong>mation must be<br />

provided, and the nature and uni<strong>for</strong>mity<br />

of this data (e.g. <strong>for</strong> comparability<br />

assessments).<br />

It may be desirable to collect data centrally<br />

156<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


that is comparable across countries. These<br />

data could help countries that are proposing<br />

national sectoral baselines and other countries<br />

and institutions to judge the stringency of the<br />

proposed baselines.<br />

Irrespective of whether these issues become a<br />

necessary part of the process of negotiations<br />

<strong>for</strong> SNLTs, it can be expected that there will<br />

be requirements <strong>for</strong> a minimum level of<br />

sophistication and per<strong>for</strong>mance of MRV systems<br />

<strong>for</strong> any such sectors. This may have the effect of<br />

ruling out some sectors in some countries where<br />

the MRV systems are not sufficiently mature.<br />

Attention to MRV issues is there<strong>for</strong>e a critical<br />

issue in the national level development and<br />

testing of the SNLT mechanism. Challenges that<br />

might be faced in this process could include<br />

the availability of data from industry <strong>for</strong> reasons<br />

such as competitiveness concerns, especially<br />

confidentiality, or institutional barriers within<br />

the industry. Furthermore, the time frame within<br />

which this has to be achieved could be difficult<br />

to set, as the amount of data that needs to be<br />

gathered might differ tremendously from country<br />

to country, not only because of the size of each<br />

country’s sector, but also because of institutional<br />

and political barriers, which might be quite<br />

different across countries.<br />

A key point regarding the issues raised above<br />

is that those groups that are already working<br />

proactively on methodologies applicable to this<br />

mechanism (e.g. sectoral proposal templates)<br />

need to obtain some indications as soon as<br />

possible from the international community as to<br />

the likely required technical specifications <strong>for</strong><br />

the in<strong>for</strong>mation and data needed to support the<br />

negotiations. This will help such groups testing<br />

the viability of this mechanism in given countries<br />

and sectors in their ongoing work.<br />

A significant issue <strong>for</strong> the negotiations that is<br />

relevant to SNLTs in particular is that it cannot<br />

be expected that every developing country that<br />

may be interested in proposing SNLTs will be<br />

ready to do so at the time that the international<br />

community expects the main details of the post-<br />

2012 multilateral climate-change deal to be<br />

agreed (e.g. in late 2009). This suggests that a<br />

doorway mechanism of some sort needs to be part<br />

of the main agreement, leaving open the option<br />

of such SNLTs to be added to the agreement at a<br />

later stage.<br />

SNLTs can be seen as one of a menu of possible<br />

international policy tools <strong>for</strong> developing<br />

countries that provide some kind of incentive.<br />

More work is needed on this timing mismatch<br />

issue, <strong>including</strong> the issue of how subsequent<br />

agreement on SNLTs may affect the targets that<br />

have already been agreed <strong>for</strong> industrialised<br />

countries. The best option seems to be <strong>for</strong><br />

the immediate implementation of accelerated<br />

capacity-building and diplomatic ef<strong>for</strong>t, such<br />

that details of potential SNLTs in some key sectors<br />

in some key countries can be well advanced<br />

by the time that industrialised countries are<br />

agreeing their next targets. The SNLT agreements<br />

could then be finalised in the period between<br />

industrialised countries agreeing their targets<br />

and the overall package of the deal being ratified<br />

by domestic governments.<br />

Given the potential importance of the SNLT<br />

mechanism, it will be desirable to find some early<br />

means to pilot test it prior to the final details of<br />

the mechanism being set. Countries that have<br />

sectors mature enough <strong>for</strong> no-lose targets could<br />

volunteer to participate. The World Bank’s <strong>new</strong><br />

A New Scaling Up Mechanism For Developing Countries<br />

157<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Carbon Partnership Facility (CPF) provides an<br />

opportunity <strong>for</strong> such piloting. It is conceivable<br />

that pilot-phase activities could be carried<br />

out <strong>for</strong> some sectors at either the national or<br />

sub-national regional levels. A number of the<br />

proposed possible pilot initiatives identified by<br />

the World Bank <strong>for</strong> the CPF, in particular largescale<br />

re<strong>new</strong>able electricity generation, could be<br />

seen as amenable to a SNLT-type mechanism.<br />

Implications <strong>for</strong> domestic policy and<br />

private-sector carbon finance<br />

A key issue <strong>for</strong> developing countries with SNLTs<br />

is how the interest of project developers and<br />

carbon financiers, whose activities thus far<br />

under the <strong>CDM</strong> have focused at the project level<br />

– <strong>including</strong>, importantly, the issuance of carbon<br />

credits – can be maintained when crediting<br />

occurs at a sector level and, in the first instance,<br />

is directed to governments.<br />

SNLT has the potential to make it much easier<br />

to mobilise the necessary inward investment and<br />

also to help strike a balance between the<br />

interests of developed and industrialised<br />

country parties to such investment.<br />

To achieve sectoral emissions reductions, national<br />

governments could implement domestic policies<br />

and measures with direct links <strong>for</strong> entities to<br />

the international carbon market, e.g. schemes<br />

that allocate credits to emissions-reduction<br />

activities by entities in the relevant sector, or by<br />

establishing internal emissions trading schemes<br />

like the EU ETS;<br />

Governments could also implement <strong>new</strong> and<br />

additional domestic policies or enhance the<br />

en<strong>for</strong>cement of existing measures that do not rely<br />

on carbon finance and emissions trading. Carbon<br />

taxes, enhanced law en<strong>for</strong>cement, intensity<br />

or efficiency standards, and subsidies (either<br />

adding or removing subsidies as the case may<br />

be <strong>for</strong> a particular sector) are examples of these<br />

types of policies and measures. Governments<br />

can then sell the received credits directly on the<br />

international carbon markets.<br />

To overcome the potential problem of the<br />

disengagement of currently active carbon market<br />

players (project developers and carbon financiers)<br />

because of concerns about having to negotiate<br />

with national governments to obtain credits, a<br />

nesting approach could be employed whereby an<br />

international institutional process akin to the<br />

current <strong>CDM</strong>, or ‘Track 2’ JI existed and credited<br />

individual on-the-ground activities. The total of<br />

any credits issued under this process would then<br />

be deducted from the amount the country was<br />

later issued <strong>for</strong> the overall sector per<strong>for</strong>mance.<br />

If a concern arises that there may be a demand–<br />

supply imbalance that would harm the carbon<br />

market (i.e. too little demand and too much supply<br />

from sectoral crediting in developing countries),<br />

a variant of the nesting approach may be to have<br />

funds provided to governments <strong>for</strong> beating their<br />

sector targets, not carbon credits.<br />

Significant institutional issues regarding capacity,<br />

legal frameworks and public compared with<br />

private can arise with all domestic implementation<br />

models. 4 Given these institutional issues, there<br />

are substantial capacity-building challenges that<br />

need to be taken up with some urgency if SNLTs<br />

4 These are assessed in some detail in Ward et al., 2008.<br />

158<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


are going to play a significant role in the next<br />

multilateral framework.<br />

Scaled-up supply needs scaled-up demand<br />

The case has been made in a range of studies<br />

<strong>for</strong> the need <strong>for</strong> the scaling-up of investments.<br />

Moreover, there seems to be an expectation<br />

that the private sector, and the carbon market<br />

specifically, will play a, if not the major role in<br />

providing this investment. But where is the<br />

market demand to come from? Discussions<br />

about enhanced mechanisms serving the supply<br />

side such as SNLTs will be affected if there is no<br />

compelling answer to this question.<br />

There are reasons <strong>for</strong> concern. Thus far, the<br />

primary demand driver of the market <strong>for</strong> CERs<br />

has been the EU ETS. The EU Commission’s 23<br />

January 2008 proposal <strong>for</strong> amendment of the<br />

ETS Directive does not provide any demand<br />

<strong>for</strong> imports from <strong>new</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> projects starting<br />

after 2012 in the absence of an international<br />

agreement. Then there is the issue of the supply<br />

of credits potentially coming from the re<strong>new</strong>al<br />

of existing <strong>CDM</strong> projects. Project activities<br />

registered <strong>for</strong> seven years can request re<strong>new</strong>al <strong>for</strong><br />

a second and third crediting period. This means<br />

that current <strong>CDM</strong> projects registered <strong>for</strong> seven<br />

years could effectively have a 21-year life-cycle if<br />

re<strong>new</strong>al does not change the baseline <strong>for</strong> these<br />

projects. For the period 2013-2020, if there is a<br />

re<strong>new</strong>al of all projects beyond their first crediting<br />

period, there is a potential supply of CERs from<br />

projects that have already been implemented<br />

or in the pipeline of about 4.8 billion CERs 5 ,<br />

thus significantly limiting the incentive <strong>for</strong> <strong>new</strong><br />

investment.<br />

5 Source: J. Fenhann, UNEP Risoe.<br />

Summarising, then, <strong>for</strong> there to be significant <strong>new</strong><br />

demand <strong>for</strong> compliance carbon commensurate<br />

with expectations on the supply side, in addition<br />

to this re<strong>new</strong>al issue needing to be addressed,<br />

industrialised countries (and not just the EU) will<br />

need to take on significant emissions-reduction<br />

obligations in the post-2012 climate deal.<br />

This demand–supply balance issue can be<br />

expected to lead to a growing awareness that<br />

mechanisms that may flood the market with large<br />

numbers of compliance credits may not be good<br />

<strong>for</strong> the overall health of the carbon market. This<br />

suggests that close attention will continue to be<br />

paid to baselines, whether these are part of <strong>CDM</strong>based<br />

mechanisms or of the <strong>for</strong>m of SNLTs.<br />

Concluding comments<br />

SNLTs are not a scaling-up silver bullet, but they<br />

have some characteristics which suggest that,<br />

<strong>for</strong> some sectors in key developing countries<br />

where very large investments are expected in<br />

the coming decades, they may be the best <strong>new</strong><br />

carbon-finance mechanism identified thus far.<br />

Moreover, in conjunction with SD-PAMs, they<br />

may be what are needed to strike the appropriate<br />

political balance with respect to mitigation<br />

between industrialised and developing countries<br />

in the post-2012 agreement. To obtain a post-<br />

2012 agreement with ambitious reduction targets<br />

ratified by industrialised countries, it is likely that<br />

they must be able to point to significantly greater<br />

commitments to mitigation actions being taken<br />

in major developing countries than has been<br />

the case under the current Kyoto agreement.<br />

And it is these ambitious reduction targets <strong>for</strong><br />

industrialised countries that create the demandside<br />

basis in the international carbon market <strong>for</strong><br />

increased investments in low-carbon technology<br />

in developing countries.<br />

A New Scaling Up Mechanism For Developing Countries<br />

159<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


However, to realise this potential, a very large ef<strong>for</strong>t<br />

is needed in a very short time. This will require<br />

proactive leadership in both industrialised and<br />

developing countries, as well as in governments<br />

and business. A tactical approach to the timing<br />

and capacity-building issues, one which may<br />

ease the political challenges, could be to identify<br />

a number of specific SNLTs in specific countries<br />

that focus on solving significant emission<br />

issues and addressing critical investment<br />

needs. Capacity-building and diplomacy ef<strong>for</strong>ts<br />

could then be directed in particular to these<br />

circumstances with a view to doing the necessary<br />

preparatory work in 2009.<br />

Some illustrative examples of such ef<strong>for</strong>ts could<br />

be SNLTs <strong>for</strong> electricity generation in China,<br />

Mexico, South Africa, India and Saudi Arabia;<br />

<strong>for</strong> cement in China, Mexico and Brazil; <strong>for</strong> iron<br />

and steel in China, India and South Africa; <strong>for</strong><br />

gas-flaring emissions in oil and gas production<br />

in Indonesia, Nigeria and Saudi Arabia; and <strong>for</strong><br />

electricity distribution in India. Note that South<br />

Korea is not listed here as it has announced its<br />

intention of proposing an economy-wide target<br />

of some <strong>for</strong>m.<br />

References<br />

Baron, R. et al. (2007) Sectoral approaches to greenhouse gas mitigation:<br />

exploring issues <strong>for</strong> heavy industry. OECD/IEA Paper.<br />

Baron, R. and Ellis, J. (2006) Sectoral crediting mechanisms <strong>for</strong> greenhouse<br />

gas mitigation: institutional and operational issues. OECD/IEA<br />

Paper, COM/ENV/EPOC/IEA/SLT(2006)4.<br />

Colombier, M. and Guerin, E. (2008) Sectoral Agreements, IDDRI.<br />

Ellis, J. and Baron, R. (2005) Sectoral Crediting <strong>Mechanisms</strong>: an initial<br />

assessment of electricity and aluminium, OECD/IEA Paper, COM/ENV/<br />

EPOC/IEA/SLT(2005)8.<br />

Schmidt, J. et al. (2006) Sector-based approaches to the post-2012<br />

climate change policy architecture, Center <strong>for</strong> Clean Air Policy (CCAP),<br />

International Future Actions Dialogue, August 2006.<br />

Ward, M. (2008) Architecture of a Global Climate Change Agreement,<br />

GtripleC.<br />

Ward, M. et al. (2008) The role of sector no-lose targets in scaling up<br />

finance <strong>for</strong> climate change mitigation activities in developing countries,<br />

UK DEFRA.<br />

Ward, M., Garibaldi, J. et al. (2008) Policy instruments and approaches<br />

<strong>for</strong> scaling up investment in climate change mitigation activities – and<br />

their interface with the World Bank’s <strong>new</strong> Carbon Partnership Facility,<br />

World Bank Carbon Finance Unit.<br />

Murray Ward is a Principal of the Global Climate Change<br />

Consultancy,providing advice to a range of international and<br />

New Zealand public and private sector clients. He previously led<br />

the New Zealand Ministry <strong>for</strong> the Environment’s climate change<br />

team and is considered one of the key architects of the Kyoto<br />

framework’s land use, <strong>for</strong>estry and market trading mechanisms.<br />

Contact: murray.ward@paradise.net.nz<br />

160<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


A New Scaling Up Mechanism For Developing Countries<br />

161<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


162<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Francisco Avendaño<br />

First Climate Group<br />

Scaling Up Ghg Emission Reductions<br />

Through Replicable Business Models<br />

Abstract<br />

This article describes promising business models<br />

to boost GHG emission reductions and aid the<br />

maturity of carbon markets. It aims to show<br />

that climate change mitigation can benefit from<br />

importing business models that are readily available<br />

in other commodities markets. The business model<br />

selected to per<strong>for</strong>m GHG mitigation can have<br />

deep consequences on the future value, scale and<br />

tradability of <strong>for</strong>ward and liquid carbon assets. This<br />

article shows the need to bring in real secondary<br />

market instruments <strong>for</strong> both supply and demand<br />

actors. Through an analogy with other commodities<br />

and practices of origination, sourcing and trading,<br />

it points out that some of the ingredients to make<br />

carbon markets work are already in existence,<br />

while others require specific amendments to<br />

current rules and carbon registries practices.<br />

The critical success factor <strong>for</strong> any post-2012<br />

climate protection agreement, yet to be reached,<br />

will be its ability to catalyze a set of replicable<br />

business models that lead to much needed GHG<br />

emissions reductions, either as a core product or<br />

as a by-product. Although the final agreement<br />

will be the result of a complex process of<br />

negotiation among UNFCCC parties, every ef<strong>for</strong>t<br />

should be made to ensure that it will be effective<br />

in implementing both the command-control and<br />

incentives measures required to boost climateprotection<br />

activities on an unprecedented scale.<br />

This article describes business models that may<br />

be used to boost climate-protection activities in<br />

a post-2012 regime.<br />

To date, the main impact of the climate change<br />

agenda on the business community has been<br />

threefold:<br />

• Carbon has a price, thanks to a steady demand<br />

<strong>for</strong> GHG reductions and emission allowances<br />

163<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


aised by a command-control approach<br />

through the legally binding commitments of<br />

Annex B Countries of the Kyoto Protocol and<br />

the EU-ETS and a growing supply developed<br />

through incentives mechanisms (<strong>CDM</strong>, JI).<br />

• Climate change is recognized as a novel<br />

factor that will modify insurance premiums<br />

<strong>for</strong> long-term operations and projects.<br />

• There is an awareness of possible climatechange<br />

impacts on food and energy security<br />

and the possible connections between<br />

biofuels and corn and sugarcane prices.<br />

The Kyoto process has led us through a learning<br />

curve regarding how to shape novel markets<br />

based on a discrete set of rules. To date, the<br />

most mature venue <strong>for</strong> reducing GHG emissions<br />

has been the Clean Development Mechanism<br />

(<strong>CDM</strong>). The future success of this mechanism<br />

or its successor depends on our ability to scale<br />

up its current applications. Current projections<br />

on future carbon credits point to 2Gt of CO2eq<br />

by 2012, and to scale this up requires a drastic<br />

reshaping of the mechanisms and the way we<br />

apply them.<br />

The paper is structured to present <strong>new</strong> ideas on<br />

how successful business practices from other<br />

markets can be designed <strong>for</strong> the carbon market<br />

in a post-2012 regime so as to achieve the desired<br />

scaling up of GHG reductions. Business practices<br />

found in other commodity markets are sketched<br />

and the modality of Programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> is<br />

introduced. Following this, the <strong>CDM</strong> Program<br />

of Activities is presented as an instrument with<br />

which secondary supply in the carbon market<br />

may be developed.. The paper concludes with<br />

some remarks and policy recommendations to<br />

enable implementation of the business models<br />

described here.<br />

Towards the maturity of carbon markets<br />

The post-2012 era will demand greater maturity<br />

and sophistication of the supply and demand sides<br />

of carbon markets. However, while the demand<br />

can be somewhat shaped by command-control<br />

measures, the supply side needs to be assisted<br />

by a considerable injection of capacity-building<br />

and by making both available and applicable<br />

instruments used in other commodity markets.<br />

Other commodity markets can be described as<br />

being composed of four elements (Figure 1).<br />

For example, the primary supply component in<br />

the market <strong>for</strong> orange juice is <strong>for</strong>med mostly<br />

by landowners or potential owners of orange<br />

plantations. The secondary supply is <strong>for</strong>med<br />

by wholesalers or aggregators, who facilitate,<br />

finance and monetize future orange-juice<br />

production in accordance with the terms set<br />

by secondary-demand actors such as food and<br />

beverage giants. Finally the readily available<br />

orange juice is inserted into logistic chains such<br />

as supermarkets, which make up the primary<br />

demand.<br />

Although carbon markets are quite young and<br />

have been progressing fast, serious ef<strong>for</strong>ts<br />

need to be undertaken to ensure that the four<br />

Figure 1. The basic structure of a mature commodity market<br />

Primary<br />

Supply<br />

Secondary<br />

Supply<br />

Secondary<br />

Demand<br />

Primary<br />

Demand<br />

164<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


asic components of a commodity market are<br />

present. In their early stage, carbon markets were<br />

mostly dominated by the demand side through<br />

the pioneering activities of governmental<br />

procurement programs and multilateral ef<strong>for</strong>ts.<br />

This was followed by an increase in the number<br />

of carbon credit suppliers and capacity-building<br />

activities to strengthen institutional capabilities<br />

(e.g. DNAs) in non-Annex B parties. This now<br />

requires to be complemented by the development<br />

of secondary market actors on the supply side<br />

who can optimize the way carbon reductions<br />

are commissioned, traded and delivered, thus<br />

resembling actors with similar roles in other<br />

markets, such as wholesalers or aggregators in the<br />

case of the coffee or orange juice markets. The<br />

element of secondary supply is of fundamental<br />

importance because it promises to open up <strong>new</strong><br />

and up to now unexplored ways of delivering<br />

carbon credits.<br />

Secondary supply in other<br />

commodity markets<br />

However, pointing to the need <strong>for</strong> wholesalers<br />

or aggregators is not enough: the instruments<br />

to make their activities possible also need<br />

to be provided. Let us examine the business<br />

model used by coffee aggregators. In this case,<br />

an aggregator or wholesaler devises a coffeesupply<br />

program according to the desired levels<br />

of homogeneity, standards and certification<br />

compliance established by the demand side.<br />

Be<strong>for</strong>e the implementation of these supply<br />

or sourcing programs, coffee production was<br />

generally scattered and atomized, and it was<br />

difficult to achieve homogeneity of quality.<br />

To illustrate how this situation was overcome,<br />

Figure 2 shows how this and other agricultural<br />

commodities with scattered production ranges<br />

are aggregated as futures. Here the aggregator or<br />

Figure 2. Secondary supply program with <strong>for</strong>ward agricultural commodities<br />

Source; prepared by the author<br />

Scaling Up Ghg Emission Reductions Through Replicable Business Models<br />

165<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


wholesaler intervenes in the design and project<br />

implementation terms to ensure full compliance<br />

with market requirements such as standards,<br />

delivery calendars and quality seals to enable<br />

trading of both <strong>for</strong>ward and spot commodities.<br />

Using PoAs <strong>for</strong> secondary carbon supply<br />

Do we have a similar instrument <strong>for</strong> carbon<br />

markets or something that can be shaped in a<br />

similar way? Yes, and it is known as Programmatic<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>. In December 2005, at the first meeting<br />

of the parties to the Kyoto Protocol (MOP1), a<br />

<strong>new</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> modality was agreed: “programmes<br />

of activities” (PoAs). PoAs are intended to open<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> market to replicable projects with low<br />

and physically scattered GHG emissions that<br />

would have been difficult and time-consuming<br />

to develop under the standard <strong>CDM</strong> model.<br />

Programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> seems to be well suited<br />

to energy efficiency, fossil-fuel switching and<br />

the use of re<strong>new</strong>able energies, particularly<br />

in private households, small enterprises and<br />

transportation. The specific rules <strong>for</strong> PoAs were<br />

developed by the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board (<strong>CDM</strong><br />

EB), which also approved the templates <strong>for</strong><br />

project-design documents <strong>for</strong> programmes of<br />

activities (PoADD) and its activities (CPADD),<br />

and issued procedures <strong>for</strong> registering PoAs<br />

and issuing CERs. The <strong>CDM</strong> EB also amended<br />

small-scale <strong>CDM</strong> methodologies to make them<br />

applicable to programmatic activities.<br />

In the past, groups of <strong>CDM</strong> projects were sometimes<br />

“bundled” to register them as one larger project<br />

or “bundling”. However, programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> has<br />

important differences. Bundling requires every<br />

single project to be identified and qualified<br />

be<strong>for</strong>e registration, while a programme can be<br />

registered at the concept level without specifying<br />

be<strong>for</strong>ehand all its constituent activities but one.<br />

Bundling has had limited success in promoting<br />

the origination and grouping of small and<br />

dispersed projects. One of the reasons <strong>for</strong> this is<br />

Fig. 3. Risk profile <strong>for</strong> a bundling scheme<br />

Project 1<br />

Icdentification &<br />

Development<br />

Project 2<br />

Project n<br />

Common<br />

Fearures<br />

Bundling<br />

PDD<br />

<strong>CDM</strong><br />

Registry<br />

Regulatory<br />

risk<br />

Source: First Climate Group<br />

Time<br />

166<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


the fact that the regulatory risk is only reduced<br />

after the bundled projects have been registered,<br />

which, as with standard <strong>CDM</strong> projects, happens<br />

only after money and ef<strong>for</strong>t have been poured<br />

into the development of every single project and<br />

the drafting of the PDD.<br />

Under the programmatic approach, regulatory<br />

risk is handled earlier in the process. Once a PoA<br />

has been registered based on a presentation of the<br />

concept and at least one real activity to the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

Executive Board, enrolled PoA participants can<br />

embark on their individual activities with greater<br />

certainty that their action will be rewarded with<br />

CERs.<br />

Under PoAs, constituent Projects are validated<br />

and verified by relevant UN-accredited Designated<br />

Operational Entities (DoE’s), while monitoring<br />

is per<strong>for</strong>med by a PoA Managing Entity.<br />

In the event of an individual activity (“CPA” in<br />

Programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> jargon) failing to comply<br />

with the registered PoA terms, the DoE reports<br />

this and the non-compliant activity is put aside.<br />

However, the other activities in the programme<br />

can continue.<br />

This feature is particularly relevant from the<br />

buyer’s perspective because the inclusion of PoAs<br />

in a portfolio offers a simple way of diversifying<br />

risk within a single type of project or technology.<br />

In addition, much of the complex management<br />

is outsourced to the managing entity, which is<br />

entitled to monitor the projects, trade CERs,<br />

distribute their benefits and represent all the<br />

programme members.<br />

To understand the advantages of a programmatic<br />

approach from the perspective of a project<br />

developer, consider an initiative to reduce GHG<br />

emissions in a given business sector. In many<br />

business sectors, there are different levels of<br />

maturity and willingness to join such an initiative.<br />

Under programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> early adopters can<br />

Fig. 4. Risk profile <strong>for</strong> a Programmatic scheme<br />

Icdentification &<br />

Development<br />

Program<br />

Concept<br />

(PoA-DD<br />

and<br />

a real CPA DD<br />

<strong>CDM</strong><br />

Registry<br />

CPA-DDs<br />

Regulatory<br />

risk<br />

Surce: First Climate Group<br />

Time<br />

Scaling Up Ghg Emission Reductions Through Replicable Business Models<br />

167<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Box 1.<br />

Latest regulatory developments<br />

to October 2008<br />

• Programmes of Activities (PoAs) can<br />

be registered by presenting the programme<br />

concept (PoA Design Document)<br />

and at least one real activity ie<br />

a <strong>CDM</strong> Programme Activity (CPA).<br />

• As <strong>new</strong> activities are identified and<br />

developed they can later be enrolled<br />

according to the terms of the registered<br />

programme.<br />

• A PoA shall use only one approved<br />

baseline and monitoring methodology,<br />

and implement only one type of<br />

technology.<br />

• Since individual CPAs may lead, in<br />

some cases, to GHG reductions<br />

below the Small Scale threshold<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> EB upgraded Small Scale<br />

Methodologies to render them<br />

applicable to PoAs. The upgrade<br />

included changes to account <strong>for</strong><br />

leakage emissions associated with<br />

PoAs<br />

Box 2.<br />

Programmatic characteristics<br />

Programmatic activities under the <strong>CDM</strong> may<br />

have the following characteristics:<br />

• There are several project developers<br />

• The projects are developed in several<br />

places at the same time<br />

• Project activities don’t start necessarily<br />

at the same time<br />

• In some cases, at the moment the program<br />

is registered it is not possible to<br />

estimate the emission reductions or the<br />

size of the whole program<br />

• The project developers are not known at<br />

the time the program is registered. Only<br />

the Managing Entity is identified.<br />

• Maximum project duration of 28 years<br />

(60 <strong>for</strong> af<strong>for</strong>estation and re<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

projects)<br />

• Depending on the registered monitoring<br />

plan, the method or approach used<br />

to verify emission may include random<br />

sampling.<br />

Source: adapted from www.unfccc.int/cdm<br />

Source: adapted from www.unfccc.int/cdm<br />

join up, while slower movers can join in as it estab<br />

lishes itself.<br />

One of the main selling points in enrolling<br />

companies in a programme is that the individual<br />

project concept has been validated and that<br />

a large part of the regulatory risk has already<br />

been taken care of by the managing entity, which<br />

registers the programme be<strong>for</strong>e the enrolling<br />

process begins.<br />

In a similar way to buying a franchise, i.e. a<br />

registered business model that works, a company<br />

participating in a programme will be able to<br />

implement a validated project without distracting<br />

itself from its core business. In practice this<br />

means that, once the PoA is registered, the<br />

Managing Entity will provide the project concept<br />

and specific recipe to companies who want to<br />

undertake emission-reductions activities framed<br />

by such a programme.<br />

168<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Experience with managing entities of PoAs<br />

So far, opportunities <strong>for</strong> this novel way of creating<br />

carbon value have been arising in business<br />

sectors that encompass small- and medium-size<br />

enterprises (SMEs), are geographically and/or<br />

temporally dispersed, and have a large number<br />

of project owners among whom the number of<br />

committed PoA members is unknown.<br />

This is often the case in the developing world,<br />

where opportunities such as residential lighting,<br />

fuel-switching, upgrading or replacing small<br />

to medium-size boilers, small landfills, water<br />

treatment systems, small hydropower stations<br />

and re<strong>for</strong>estation programmes may proliferate<br />

thanks to programmatic <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

PoAs are also seen as an opportunity to<br />

strengthen environmental reporting and<br />

governance in atomised business sectors. In<br />

developing economies, governments prioritise<br />

the allocation of their scarce environmental<br />

law en<strong>for</strong>cement budget on large-scale industry<br />

and natural resource extraction operations,<br />

leaving SMEs unmonitored. For instance, in<br />

most developing countries, small hydropower<br />

plants below a certain capacity (e.g. 10 MW) do<br />

not need to conduct an environmental impact<br />

assessment, but only present a statement and a<br />

brief environmental management plan, which will<br />

rarely be audited or followed up by government<br />

bureaus.<br />

Fig. 5. Secondary supply with <strong>for</strong>ward CERs coming from PoAs.<br />

The business of coping with climate change has grown more rapidly than previous ef<strong>for</strong>ts in any environmental field and has<br />

served as a Trojan horse to intervene deeply into corporate agendas and boost participation in climate-neutral activities and<br />

voluntary carbon markets.<br />

Source: prepared by the author<br />

Scaling Up Ghg Emission Reductions Through Replicable Business Models<br />

169<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


However, if owners of small hydropower installations<br />

are enrolled in a PoA, the managing entity is<br />

entitled to monitor and report their environmental<br />

per<strong>for</strong>mance, safeguarding the compliance of<br />

PoA terms, which would include ecological issues,<br />

sound stakeholder relationships, applicable law<br />

compliance, and so on.<br />

Another issue to consider is that the project has<br />

to be evaluated from both the programme and<br />

the project-by-project perspectives. For example,<br />

Once the PoA is registered, the Managing<br />

Entity will provide the project concept<br />

and specific recipe to companies who<br />

want to undertake emission-reductions<br />

activities framed by such a programme.<br />

the PoA must indicate at registration the specific<br />

in<strong>for</strong>mation to be provided (from each CPA) to<br />

ensure that leakage, additionality, establishment<br />

of the baseline, baseline emissions, eligibility<br />

and double counting are properly addressed by<br />

each CPA within the PoA.<br />

How can PoAs be used as instruments to bring<br />

maturity to carbon markets? In a similar way<br />

to the business model used by the coffee or<br />

orange juice sectors, Programmatic <strong>CDM</strong> would<br />

enable aggregators to act as the managing<br />

entities of a PoA. Through this modality, the<br />

aggregator or managing entity can ensure that<br />

the GHG reductions achieved by its constituent<br />

activities (CPAs) comply with the desired levels<br />

of homogeneity (same technology), standards<br />

(same baseline methodology) and certification<br />

(<strong>CDM</strong> registration), as well as intrinsic risk<br />

diversification, see Figure 5.<br />

Final remarks and policy recommendations<br />

To boost carbon supply (demand can be enhanced<br />

depending on the outcome of the Bali roadmap),<br />

primary demand needs to be aggregated<br />

through the use of more sophisticated means<br />

(e.g. PoAs) than simply visiting project owners<br />

and purchase/finance projects individually. An<br />

aggregator or wholesaler (e.g. PoA Managing<br />

Entity), a common actor in mature markets,<br />

has far greater opportunities to align actual<br />

supply with demand terms and conditions,<br />

<strong>including</strong> the provision of delivery guarantees,<br />

monetization of carbon contracts, financing<br />

in local terms (which enhances liquidity and<br />

collection possibilities in case of default) and<br />

local due-diligence practices according to the<br />

reality found frequently in companies operating<br />

in developing countries. It may be even possible,<br />

as in other commodity markets, to have several<br />

PoAs <strong>for</strong> the same technology and project type<br />

within the same physical areas, thus giving<br />

rise to healthy competition to offer the best<br />

combination of effectiveness, managing entity<br />

fees and PoA support.<br />

PoAs promise to play a major role in strengthening<br />

secondary carbon supply and carbon markets<br />

maturity in general. To facilitate this development,<br />

the following decisions need to be taken as part<br />

of the Bali roadmap:<br />

• A successor to the <strong>CDM</strong> should be defined.<br />

Post-2012 GHG reductions coming from<br />

project activities registered as <strong>CDM</strong> be<strong>for</strong>e<br />

31 December 2012 are eligible to be<br />

certified as tradable carbon credits usable or<br />

swappable by other types of carbon credits,<br />

thus giving rise to a truly global carbon<br />

credit commodity.<br />

• A global carbon credit registry should allow<br />

<strong>for</strong> transactions among permanent non-<br />

170<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Annex I accounts, thus producing a dynamic<br />

secondary market on the selling side. This will<br />

invite local and regional banks and domestic<br />

actors (technology-providers, business<br />

groups, etc.) to think and act seriously about<br />

carbon origination.<br />

• Eliminate the 1-km limit <strong>for</strong> neighbouring<br />

distance (see debundling tool at EB33<br />

Report Annex 21) between registered CPAs<br />

belonging to the same SSC PoA. The 1-km<br />

limit can be replaced <strong>for</strong> a multiphase plan<br />

presented be<strong>for</strong>e PoA implementation so that<br />

a distinction between “future” neighbouring<br />

CPAs and actual attempts to split a big<br />

project can be spotted without inhibiting<br />

the implementation of efficient lighting and<br />

energy efficiency PoAs <strong>for</strong> the residential and<br />

commercial sectors and other project types.<br />

• The pros and cons of having a price<br />

regulation mechanism (e.g. a carbon central<br />

bank to bring equilibrium to the CER/EUA<br />

and other carbon credit types “exchange<br />

rates”) should be considered.<br />

Furthermore, the private sector should be able<br />

to:<br />

• Improve the capitalization of GHG reductions<br />

obtained by day-to-day capital management<br />

in non-Annex B countries. For example, two<br />

multilateral financial institutions injected<br />

capital into two different instruments: a<br />

domestic credit line <strong>for</strong> energy efficiency<br />

and GHG reductions; and a fund to finance<br />

low-emission electricity projects. The first<br />

initiative was simply coupled with the<br />

practices and contracting structures of the<br />

domestic bank that was used to allocate<br />

the loans. The loans were quickly allocated,<br />

but the bank failed to capitalize on GHG<br />

reductions of loan receivers, thus leaving<br />

them on their own in terms of carbon<br />

development support. If local and regional<br />

The critical success factor <strong>for</strong> any post-<br />

2012 climate protection agreement, yet to<br />

be reached, will be its ability to catalyze a<br />

set of replicable business models that lead<br />

to much needed GHG emissions reductions,<br />

either as a core product or as a by-product.<br />

banks were to be properly equipped to<br />

capitalize on GHG reductions, this failure<br />

would not happen again. The second<br />

initiative proved to be very fruitful where<br />

the operator assembled a sound portfolio<br />

of clean electricity projects across a region,<br />

capitalizing not only on GHG reductions<br />

but also increasing the market value of the<br />

portfolio holder as a whole. Opportunities<br />

like this have been identified by the main<br />

global electricity suppliers who now value<br />

not only having supply capacity, but also<br />

a good share of clean electricity installed<br />

capacity.<br />

• PoAs should be used as carbon credit supply<br />

tools or as secondary supply or sourcing tools.<br />

Future supply can be boosted if aggregators<br />

or wholesalers intervene at an early stage<br />

in enrolling projects or companies in <strong>CDM</strong><br />

programmes (PoAs).<br />

Francisco Avendaño has worked extensively in the USA, EU and<br />

Latin America on energy, commodities markets, and climate change,<br />

<strong>including</strong> professional posts with Shell International, the Peruvian<br />

DNA, and the International Emissions Trading Association (IETA).<br />

Contact: francisco.avendano@firstclimate.com<br />

Scaling Up Ghg Emission Reductions Through Replicable Business Models<br />

171<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


172<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Marcelo Theoto Rocha<br />

University of Sao Paulo<br />

LULUCF under <strong>CDM</strong>:<br />

Is there a role or even a future<br />

in the post-2012 regime?<br />

Abstract:<br />

The post-2012 climate regime is under negotiation.<br />

Until now af<strong>for</strong>estation and re<strong>for</strong>estation project<br />

activities have enjoyed extremely low participation<br />

in the carbon market. The principal reasons<br />

are that they are not accepted in the EU-ETS<br />

and that they generate only temporary credits.<br />

The future of these project activities in the<br />

post-2012 regime is unclear, as are the role and<br />

financing mechanisms <strong>for</strong> reducing emissions from<br />

de<strong>for</strong>estation and <strong>for</strong>est degradation (REDD).<br />

The aim of this paper is to explain the current<br />

role of LULUCF and the limitations in the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

and offer some ideas <strong>for</strong> possible improvements.<br />

The Kyoto Protocol of the United Nations<br />

Framework Convention on Climate Change<br />

(UNFCCC) allows developed countries with<br />

greenhouse gas (GHG) reduction commitments<br />

to buy certified emissions reductions (CERs) to<br />

meet their targets. The CERs are to be generated<br />

through project activities under the Clean<br />

Development Mechanism (<strong>CDM</strong>), as defined in<br />

Article 12 of the Kyoto Protocol. Different types<br />

of project activity may be developed under the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>, <strong>including</strong> land use, land-use change and<br />

<strong>for</strong>estry (LULUCF).<br />

According to the current rules of the <strong>CDM</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

the first commitment period 2008-2012, only<br />

af<strong>for</strong>estation and re<strong>for</strong>estation (A/R) project<br />

activities are eligible under all potential LULUCF<br />

activities. These kinds of project enjoy extremely<br />

low demand among buyers in the carbon<br />

market. In order to increase the number of A/R<br />

173<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


projects in the carbon market and to explore<br />

the potential of other LULUCF activities, such<br />

as reducing emissions from de<strong>for</strong>estation and<br />

<strong>for</strong>est degradation (REDD), it is necessary to<br />

revise the current modalities and procedures.<br />

The main aim of this paper is to offer some “food<br />

<strong>for</strong> thought” to help negotiate LULUCF ‘s role in<br />

the post-2012 regime.<br />

Until now af<strong>for</strong>estation and re<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

project activities have enjoyed extremely<br />

low participation in the carbon market;<br />

the principal reasons are that they are<br />

not accepted in the EU-ETS and that<br />

they generate only temporary credits.<br />

Specifically, the aims of this paper are to explain<br />

the genesis of the current rules related to A/R<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> projects activities; identify the main<br />

reasons <strong>for</strong> the low participation of A/R <strong>CDM</strong><br />

projects activities in the carbon market; propose<br />

modifications to the current A/R rules <strong>for</strong> the<br />

post-2012 climate regime; and discuss the<br />

potential <strong>for</strong> <strong>including</strong> project activities related<br />

to REDD in the <strong>CDM</strong> under the post-2012 climate<br />

regime.<br />

For this purpose, the paper is divided into the<br />

following sections: the present introduction; the<br />

history of LULUCF negotiations under the Kyoto<br />

Protocol; the experience gained from current<br />

projects and methodologies; proposals <strong>for</strong><br />

improvements to the current rules; the particular<br />

case of reducing emissions from de<strong>for</strong>estation and<br />

<strong>for</strong>est degradation (REDD); and conclusions.<br />

The history of LULUCF negotiations<br />

under the Kyoto Protocol<br />

In 2003, at the 9 th Conference of the Parties<br />

(COP 9) to the UNFCCC, delegates from different<br />

countries worked hard to finish discussions and<br />

to agree on the “modalities and procedures <strong>for</strong><br />

A/R project activities under the <strong>CDM</strong> in the<br />

first commitment period of the Kyoto Protocol”<br />

(Decision 19/CP.9). 1<br />

The negotiations started just after the conclusion<br />

of the Marrakesh Accords (agreed in 2001 at<br />

COP 7), and had as their main guide the decision<br />

related to LULUCF (Decision 11/CP.7) 2 and the<br />

modalities and procedures <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> (Decision<br />

17/CP.7). 3<br />

To guarantee the environmental integrity of the<br />

Kyoto Protocol, Decision 11/CP.7 affirms that<br />

the treatment of LULUCF activities must be<br />

governed by certain principles (see Box 1). The<br />

principles should be applied in all commitment<br />

periods of the Kyoto Protocol and have the aim<br />

of guaranteeing that the removals obtained<br />

through LULUCF activities are real, measurable<br />

and verifiable. Special attention should be given<br />

to principle g: “That reversal of any removal due to<br />

land use, land-use change and <strong>for</strong>estry activities<br />

be accounted <strong>for</strong> at the appropriate point in time”.<br />

Because of this principle, the removals from A/R<br />

project activities were considered temporary in<br />

the development of the current A/R <strong>CDM</strong> rules.<br />

Decision 11/CP.7 also adopted definitions, modal<br />

ities, rules and guidelines relating to LULUCF<br />

1 After Kyoto Protocol entered into <strong>for</strong>ce, became Decision 5/CMP.1 (<br />

http://cdm.unfccc.int/Reference/COPMOP/08a01.pdf#page=61)<br />

2 After Kyoto Protocol entered into <strong>for</strong>ce, became Decision 16/CMP.1 (<br />

http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2005/cmp1/eng/08a03.pdf#page=3)<br />

3 After Kyoto Protocol entered into <strong>for</strong>ce, became Decision 3/CMP.1 (<br />

http://cdm.unfccc.int/Reference/COPMOP/08a01.pdf#page=6)<br />

174<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


activities, <strong>for</strong> application in the first commitment<br />

period. It is important to highlight that the<br />

decision was agreed only <strong>for</strong> the first commitment<br />

period, because of which it is possible to revise<br />

the content of such decisions in the negotiations<br />

over the post-2012 climate regime. The decision<br />

clearly states that: “The treatment of LULUCF<br />

project activities under Article 12 in future<br />

commitment periods shall be decided as part<br />

of the negotiations on the second commitment<br />

period”.<br />

For the <strong>CDM</strong>, Decision 11/CP.7 limited the eligibility<br />

of LULUCF project activities to af<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

and re<strong>for</strong>estation. In both cases, project<br />

proponents need to encourage the conversion<br />

of land without <strong>for</strong>est to <strong>for</strong>ested land through<br />

planting, seeding and/or the human-induced<br />

promotion of natural seed sources. The only<br />

difference between af<strong>for</strong>estation and re<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

is the period of time during which the project<br />

proponent needs to check the “non-<strong>for</strong>est status”<br />

of the land. For af<strong>for</strong>estation no <strong>for</strong>est must have<br />

grown on the land <strong>for</strong> a period of at least fifty<br />

years. For re<strong>for</strong>estation projects, the proponent<br />

need only check the status of the land as of 31<br />

December 1989.<br />

The possibility of <strong>including</strong> REDD in the <strong>CDM</strong><br />

was there<strong>for</strong>e excluded <strong>for</strong> the first commitment<br />

period (see further discussions on REDD in the<br />

section below).<br />

Decision 11/CP.7 also established that: “the<br />

total of additions to a Party’s assigned amount<br />

resulting from eligible LULUCF project activities<br />

under the <strong>CDM</strong> shall not exceed one per cent of<br />

base year emissions of that Party, times five”. This<br />

means that there is a limit to the amount of CERs<br />

from A/R <strong>CDM</strong> project activities that a developed<br />

country can use to meet its target. According to<br />

BOX 1.<br />

Principles related to LULUCF<br />

adopted in Decision 11 CP.7<br />

a. That the treatment of these activities<br />

be based on sound science;<br />

b. That consistent methodologies be<br />

used over time <strong>for</strong> the estimation<br />

and reporting of these activities;<br />

c. That the aim stated in Article 3,<br />

paragraph 1, of the Kyoto Protocol<br />

not be changed by accounting <strong>for</strong><br />

land use, land-use change and <strong>for</strong>estry<br />

activities;<br />

d. That the mere presence of carbon<br />

stocks be excluded from accounting;<br />

e. That the implementation of land use,<br />

land-use change and <strong>for</strong>estry activities<br />

contributes to the conservation<br />

of biodiversity and sustainable use of<br />

natural resources;<br />

f. That accounting <strong>for</strong> land use, landuse<br />

change and <strong>for</strong>estry does not<br />

imply a transfer of commitments to a<br />

future commitment period;<br />

g. That reversal of any removal due<br />

to land use, land-use change and<br />

<strong>for</strong>estry activities be accounted <strong>for</strong><br />

at the appropriate point in time; and,<br />

h. That accounting excludes removals<br />

resulting from:<br />

(i) elevated carbon dioxide concentrations<br />

above their pre-industrial<br />

level;<br />

(ii) indirect nitrogen deposition; and<br />

(iii) the dynamic effects of age<br />

structure resulting from activities and<br />

practices be<strong>for</strong>e the reference year.<br />

Is there a role or even a future in the post-2012 regime?<br />

175<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Bernoux et al. (2002), 4 the market size <strong>for</strong> A/R<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> carbon credits would only be about 110 Mt<br />

CO 2<br />

<strong>for</strong> the first commitment period of the Kyoto<br />

Protocol.<br />

While Decision 11/CP.7 laid down the principles,<br />

definitions and limits <strong>for</strong> inclusion of LULUCF<br />

activities under the <strong>CDM</strong>, decision 17/CP.7<br />

provided a “legal structure”, i.e. the headings and a<br />

first negotiating text on the basis of which delegates<br />

negotiated the specific modalities and procedures<br />

<strong>for</strong> A/R project activities under the <strong>CDM</strong>.<br />

During the negotiations, many countries had<br />

strong reservations, in some cases even raising<br />

objections, to LULUCF project activities. Deep<br />

differences appeared on many aspects, such as<br />

the date <strong>for</strong> the definition of re<strong>for</strong>estation and<br />

how to treat the non-permanence of the removals<br />

from the <strong>for</strong>estry (principle g of Decision 11/<br />

CP7). As a result conclusions were delayed until<br />

2003 at COP 9, where the Parties agreed on the<br />

modalities and procedures regarding A/R <strong>CDM</strong><br />

project activities (Decision 19/CP.9).<br />

Because of such divergences, it is important to<br />

recall that Decision19/CP.9 also decided: 5<br />

and<br />

that the treatment of LULUCF project activities<br />

under the <strong>CDM</strong> in future commitment periods<br />

shall be decided as part of the negotiations on<br />

the second commitment period and that any revision<br />

of the decision shall not affect A/R project<br />

activities under the <strong>CDM</strong> registered prior to the<br />

end of the first commitment period;<br />

to periodically review the modalities and procedures<br />

<strong>for</strong> A/R project activities under the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>, and that the first review shall be<br />

carried out no later than one year be<strong>for</strong>e<br />

the end of the first commitment period,<br />

based on recommendations by the Executive<br />

Board of the <strong>CDM</strong> and by the Subsidiary<br />

Body <strong>for</strong> Implementation, drawing on<br />

technical advice from the Subsidiary Body<br />

<strong>for</strong> Scientific and Technological Advice, as<br />

needed.<br />

These passages clearly give a legal mandate<br />

to try and improve the current rules. These<br />

improvements are necessary since few A/R <strong>CDM</strong><br />

project activities are being proposed. They also<br />

represent a “political will” that existed in 2003<br />

but may now be lost in the negotiations <strong>for</strong> a<br />

post-2012 climate regime.<br />

The experience learned from current<br />

projects and methodologies<br />

According to the UNEP Risø Centre, 6 on 1<br />

September 2008 there were 3,819 <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activities in the pipeline. Of this total, only five<br />

project activities relate to af<strong>for</strong>estation and 22<br />

to re<strong>for</strong>estation. This represents only 0.13% and<br />

0.58% respectively of the projects in the pipeline<br />

and, in terms of potential 2012 CERs, only 0.07%<br />

and 0.43% respectively.<br />

The extreme low participation of A/R <strong>CDM</strong><br />

project activities in the carbon market cannot be<br />

explained by the lack of methodologies as in the<br />

past. At the time of writing, fourteen baseline and<br />

monitoring methodologies had been approved<br />

by the Executive Board. 7 This means that project<br />

4 Bernoux, M.; Eschenbrenner, V.; Cerri, C.C.; Melillo, J.M.; Feller, C.<br />

LULUCF-based <strong>CDM</strong>: too much ado <strong>for</strong>... a small carbon market.<br />

Climate Policy 2 (2002) 379–385.<br />

5 See http://cdm.unfccc.int/Reference/COPMOP/08a01.<br />

pdf#page=61 paragraph 3 and 4.<br />

6 UNEP Risoe <strong>CDM</strong>/JI Pipeline Analysis and Database, September 1st<br />

2008 - http://www.cdmpipeline.org/publications/<strong>CDM</strong>pipeline.xls<br />

7 http://cdm.unfccc.int/methodologies/ARmethodologies/index.html<br />

176<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


proponents have fourteen different methodologies<br />

to determine and estimate the baseline 8 and the<br />

“net anthropogenic greenhouse gas removals by<br />

sinks”. 9 Probably around 80% of all potential A/R<br />

project activities under the <strong>CDM</strong> are covered by<br />

the approved methodologies.<br />

Different reasons explain the extremely low<br />

participation of A/R <strong>CDM</strong> project activities in<br />

the carbon market. In order of importance, the<br />

main reasons are:<br />

1. No acceptance under the EU ETS (European<br />

Union Emission Trade Scheme):<br />

the European Union does not buy CERs<br />

from A/R <strong>CDM</strong> to comply with its emission<br />

reductions targets, with the arguments<br />

that: 10<br />

• “LULUCF projects cannot physically<br />

deliver permanent emissions<br />

reductions. Insufficient solutions<br />

have been developed to deal with<br />

the uncertainties, non-permanence<br />

of carbon storage and potential<br />

emissions ‘leakage’ problems arising<br />

from such projects. The temporary<br />

and reversible nature of such activities<br />

would pose considerable risks in a<br />

company-based trading system and<br />

impose great liability risks on Member<br />

States;<br />

8 The baseline scenario <strong>for</strong> an A/R <strong>CDM</strong> project activity is the<br />

scenario that reasonably represents the sum of the changes in carbon<br />

stocks in the carbon pools within the project boundary that would have<br />

occurred in the absence of the proposed project activity (http://cdm.<br />

unfccc.int/Reference/Guidclarif/glos_<strong>CDM</strong>_v04.pdf)<br />

9 Defined as ’the actual net GHG removals by sinks minus the baseline<br />

net GHG removals by sinks minus leakage’ http://cdm.unfccc.int/Reference/Guidclarif/glos_<strong>CDM</strong>_v04.pdf<br />

10 Questions and Answers on the Commission’s proposal to revise<br />

the EU Emissions Trading System - MEMO/08/35 (23/01/2008).<br />

Available at: http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.<br />

do?reference=MEMO/08/35<br />

• The inclusion of LULUCF projects in<br />

the ETS would require a quality of<br />

monitoring and reporting comparable<br />

to the monitoring and reporting of<br />

emissions from installations currently<br />

There are high expectations concerning<br />

the positive incentives that could come<br />

from REDD, especially in countries<br />

that see REDD as the only profitable<br />

way to enter the “carbon market”.<br />

covered by the system. This is not<br />

available at present and is likely to<br />

incur costs which would substantially<br />

reduce the attractiveness of <strong>including</strong><br />

such projects.<br />

• The simplicity, transparency and<br />

predictability of the ETS would be<br />

considerably reduced. Moreover, the<br />

sheer quantity of potential credits<br />

entering the system could undermine<br />

the functioning of the carbon market<br />

unless their role were limited, in<br />

which case their potential benefits<br />

would become marginal.” 11<br />

2. Temporary credits: In order to take into<br />

consideration one of the main concerns<br />

of Parties, namely the potential non-permanence<br />

of the <strong>for</strong>est (principle g of Decision<br />

11/CP.7), decision 19/CP.9, introducing<br />

temporary credits <strong>for</strong> A/R <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activities, was adopted. There are two types<br />

of temporary credit: i) “Temporary CER”<br />

11 Questions and Answers on the Commission’s proposal to revise the<br />

EU Emissions Trading System (MEMO/08/35) – available at: http://<br />

ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/emission/ets_post2012_en.htm<br />

Is there a role or even a future in the post-2012 regime?<br />

177<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


(tCER), which expires at the end of the<br />

commitment period following the one<br />

during which it was issued. For example, a<br />

tCER issued in 2007 will expire at the end<br />

of the first commitment period, e.g. 31 December<br />

2012; ii) “Long-term CER” (lCER),<br />

which expires at the end of the crediting<br />

period of the A/R <strong>CDM</strong> project activity. For<br />

example, if an lCER is issued in 2007 and<br />

the A/R <strong>CDM</strong> project activity has a crediting<br />

period of 30 years, the lCER will<br />

expire in 2037. In this sense, the temporary<br />

credits from A/R <strong>CDM</strong> project activities<br />

can be considered a “rent”, where the<br />

project proponent undertakes the obligation<br />

to remove and retain a certain quantity<br />

of CO 2<br />

during a specific period of time.<br />

At the end of the rent contract, the project<br />

proponent is free to release the CO 2<br />

(cut<br />

the <strong>for</strong>est), and the buyer must replace the<br />

credit.<br />

3. Complexity and cost of the approved<br />

baseline and monitoring methodologies:<br />

One of the main complaints of project developers<br />

is that the A/R methodologies are,<br />

in most cases, relatively more complex and<br />

costly than non-A/R methodologies.<br />

4. Limits on the use of tCERs or lCERS:<br />

As already pointed out ,the total amount<br />

of carbon credits from A/R <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activities that can be used by developed<br />

countries to meet their emission reduction<br />

target under the first commitment period<br />

of the Kyoto Protocol is limited. For other<br />

reasons, nowadays even the limit is not<br />

achieved.<br />

Proposals <strong>for</strong> improvements<br />

to the current rules<br />

Among the reasons cited above, reason 3 (and<br />

the monitoring quality raised by the EU) could be<br />

dealt with in the context of the Af<strong>for</strong>estation and<br />

Re<strong>for</strong>estation Working Group (AR-WG) under<br />

the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board (EB). The AR-WG was<br />

established to draw up, among other things:<br />

recommendations on options <strong>for</strong> expanding the<br />

applicability of methodologies <strong>for</strong> <strong>CDM</strong> A/R<br />

project activities, if applicable, and develop tools<br />

to facilitate the selection of one approved methodology<br />

from among those of a similar nature by<br />

project participants. 12<br />

The work of the group is similar to the<br />

Methodologies Panel (Meth Panel).<br />

In this sense, the consolidation process started<br />

with methodology AR-ACM0001 is very welcome. 13<br />

Further consolidations could be used to simplify<br />

the methodologies, taking into consideration, of<br />

course, the environmental integrity of the Kyoto<br />

Protocol. A deeper look at the methodologies<br />

from non-<strong>for</strong>estry project activities might inspire<br />

the process. Also, the development of tools could<br />

represent a powerful simplification, especially<br />

if they could be accompanied by user-friendly<br />

software. Of course, if AR-WG is guided only by<br />

an “academic spirit “, consolidation and tools<br />

could have the opposite effect of simplification<br />

by creating methodologies that are more complex<br />

and costly.<br />

12 Terms of reference <strong>for</strong> the af<strong>for</strong>estation and re<strong>for</strong>estation working<br />

group (EB23, Annex14)<br />

13 Af<strong>for</strong>estation and re<strong>for</strong>estation of degraded land - Version 1 (http://<br />

cdm.unfccc.int/UserManagement/FileStorage/<strong>CDM</strong>_ACMMEBS-<br />

DU565IKTQC14YSI0WK3BVUYN02)<br />

178<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


However, the most important reasons (1 and<br />

2) <strong>for</strong> the low participation of AR <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activities in the carbon market can only be solved<br />

by political decisions.<br />

According to the directive proposal <strong>for</strong> EU ETS<br />

Phase III 14 (2012 to 2020), A/R <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activities will still be banned. The EU needs to<br />

revise its reasons <strong>for</strong> not accepting A/R <strong>CDM</strong><br />

project activities and even propose different ways<br />

to deal with the issue of non-permanence.<br />

In the UNFCCC context, the recent conclusions<br />

of the Ad Hoc Working Group on Further<br />

Commitments <strong>for</strong> Annex I Parties under the Kyoto<br />

Protocol (AWG-KP) 15 acknowledged that further<br />

discussions on LULUCF should take into account<br />

the principles established by decision 11/CP.7. In<br />

relation to the project-based mechanisms there<br />

are two possible approaches:<br />

(a) Make a few changes in the current rules, meaning<br />

that only the legally required changes will be made<br />

to the current modalities and procedures (the<br />

same rules will apply mutatis mutandis <strong>for</strong> post-<br />

2012, and only the reference to the first commitment<br />

period will be deleted from the rules);<br />

(b) Make more changes to current rules, meaning that<br />

non-permanence, leakage, measurements, definitions<br />

and others elements could be revisited as<br />

necessary.<br />

In both arenas (EU ETS and UNFCCC), first of<br />

all, there is a need <strong>for</strong> “political will” to make<br />

real revisions and possible improvements to the<br />

current modalities and procedures. “Political<br />

will” in this context means that countries need to<br />

14 http://ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/emission/ets_post2012_<br />

en.htm<br />

15 For example: FCCC/KP/AWG/2008/L.5 - http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2008/awg5/eng/l05.pdf<br />

agree that LULUCF project activities can or should<br />

play a bigger role in the post-2012 regime. Some of<br />

the limitations that project activities may have (e.g.<br />

non-permanence and monitoring costs) could be<br />

solved by a real learning-by-doing approach or by<br />

being treated differently in specific situations, even if<br />

they produce losses in “simplicity, transparency<br />

and predictability”. Also, there is always the<br />

possibility to define acceptable losses in<br />

“simplicity, transparency and predictability”.<br />

If the temporary credits solution remains<br />

in the post-2012 regime and will also be<br />

applied to REDD credits, then probably<br />

the demand <strong>for</strong> LULUCF <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activities will remain extremely low, being<br />

incapable of raising the amount of financial<br />

resources needed to make LULUCF a real<br />

contribution to climate-change mitigation.<br />

During the process of agreeing Decision 19/CP.9<br />

(2003), there was a “political will” that predicted<br />

the revision of the modalities and procedures<br />

(see quote above) after experiences were made.<br />

Un<strong>for</strong>tunately, the current modalities and<br />

procedures did not create the necessary number<br />

of projects to make up a diverse, concrete and<br />

real experience. In other non-<strong>for</strong>est cases, the<br />

improvements were only possible due to experience<br />

learned from concrete projects (e.g. monitoring of<br />

CH4 emissions in manure management projects<br />

and landfill ex-ante estimates).<br />

Now, in the current discussions on the role of<br />

LULUCF post-2012, especially in the AWG-KP, it<br />

seems that some Parties do not have the strong<br />

political will needed to discuss the issue further.<br />

Is there a role or even a future in the post-2012 regime?<br />

179<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


If parties really want to create more space <strong>for</strong><br />

LULUCF projects in the post-2012 regime,<br />

it is necessary to demonstrate some trust in<br />

these kinds of project and to explore <strong>new</strong> ideas<br />

regarding the challenges and, if necessary, pay<br />

the costs of developing such ideas.<br />

With regard to non-permanence, one <strong>new</strong> idea<br />

to be explored further is to establish some kind<br />

of <strong>for</strong>est (native <strong>for</strong>est without any commercial<br />

exploration) in countries with a legal and en<strong>for</strong>ceable<br />

framework <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>est protection. The<br />

<strong>for</strong>est could be subjected to low-cost monitoring<br />

procedures after the final verification with the<br />

aim of extending permanence beyond the current<br />

time limit imposed by the temporary credits.<br />

After the end of the crediting period, the carbon<br />

credits created remain valid as long as the project<br />

proponent demonstrates evidence that the <strong>for</strong>est<br />

remains on the ground. Such evidence could be<br />

limited to satellite images or photographs every<br />

five years, after the last verification. It would not<br />

require further carbon stock measurements after<br />

the last verification, assuming that the <strong>for</strong>est<br />

does not enter in a process of degradation after<br />

establishment.<br />

Other ideas to deal with the non-permanence<br />

issue include the establishment of buffer zones<br />

that could serve as a <strong>for</strong>m of insurance, and host<br />

countries assuming the liability of the “reversal<br />

of any removal”. All of them could have high cost.<br />

It is important to emphasize that the technical<br />

debates should be started without the “political<br />

will” and will probably repeat discussions and<br />

conclusions from 2003, i.e. the “temporary<br />

credits”. Finally, caps (as explained in reason 4)<br />

could still be used in order to accommodate<br />

concerns regarding environmental integrity.<br />

BOX 2.<br />

Indicative guidance <strong>for</strong> REDD<br />

demonstration activities<br />

1. Demonstration activities should be undertaken<br />

with the approval of the host Party.<br />

2. Estimates of reductions or increases in emissions<br />

should be results-based, demonstrable,<br />

transparent, verifiable, and estimated<br />

consistently over time.<br />

3. The use of the methodologies (Good<br />

Practice Guidance <strong>for</strong> Land Use, Land-Use<br />

Change and Forestry) is encouraged as a<br />

basis <strong>for</strong> estimating and monitoring emissions.<br />

4. Emission reductions from national demonstration<br />

activities should be assessed on the<br />

basis of national emissions from de<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

and <strong>for</strong>est degradation.<br />

5. Subnational demonstration activities should<br />

be assessed within the boundary used <strong>for</strong><br />

the demonstration, and assessed <strong>for</strong> associated<br />

displacement of emissions.<br />

6. Reductions in emissions or increases resulting<br />

from the demonstration activity should<br />

be based on historical emissions, taking into<br />

account national circumstances.<br />

7. Subnational approaches, where applied,<br />

should constitute a step towards the development<br />

of national approaches, reference<br />

levels and estimates.<br />

8. Demonstration activities should be consistent<br />

with sustainable <strong>for</strong>est management,<br />

noting, inter alia, the relevant provisions<br />

of the United Nations Forum on Forests,<br />

the United Nations Convention to Combat<br />

Desertification and the Convention on<br />

Biological Diversity.<br />

9. Experiences in implementing activities<br />

should be reported and made available via<br />

the Web plat<strong>for</strong>m<br />

10. Reporting on demonstration activities<br />

should include a description of the activities<br />

and their effectiveness, and may include<br />

other in<strong>for</strong>mation.<br />

11.<br />

Independent expert review is encouraged.<br />

180<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


The particular case of REDD<br />

Reducing emissions from de<strong>for</strong>estation and <strong>for</strong>est<br />

degradation (REDD) is becoming more attractive<br />

than af<strong>for</strong>estation and re<strong>for</strong>estation, at least in<br />

the negotiations. There are high expectations<br />

from various countries about the outcome of the<br />

negotiations. The negotations re-started in 2005,<br />

when the Government of Papua New Guinea by<br />

its communication dated 28 July 2005, requested<br />

the secretariat to add an item titled ‘Reducing<br />

emissions from de<strong>for</strong>estation in developing<br />

countries: approaches to stimulate action’ to<br />

the provisional agenda of the Conference of the<br />

Parties at its eleventh session.<br />

After the initial submission from Papua New<br />

Guinea and Costa Rica, 16 many other submissions<br />

were made, workshops were held, and a decision<br />

was taken in Bali in the context of the “Road<br />

Map” 17 . The main element in that decision is the<br />

possibility of Parties to undertake “demonstration<br />

activities” following indicative guidance (see Box<br />

2).<br />

Countries are working on the development of<br />

these demonstration activities, especially with<br />

the help of the Forest Carbon Partnership<br />

Facility from the World Bank.<br />

The <strong>new</strong> Forest Carbon Partnership Facility is designed<br />

to set the stage <strong>for</strong> a large-scale system<br />

of incentives <strong>for</strong> reducing emissions from de<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

and <strong>for</strong>est degradation, providing a fresh<br />

source of financing <strong>for</strong> the sustainable use of<br />

<strong>for</strong>est resources and biodiversity conservation....<br />

The Forest Carbon Partnership Facility will build<br />

the capacity of developing countries in tropical<br />

and subtropical regions to reduce emissions from<br />

de<strong>for</strong>estation and <strong>for</strong>est degradation and to tap<br />

into any future system of positive incentives <strong>for</strong><br />

REDD. In some of these countries, the FCPF will<br />

also help reduce the rate of de<strong>for</strong>estation and <strong>for</strong>est<br />

degradation by providing an incentive per ton<br />

of carbon dioxide of emissions reduced through<br />

specific Emission Reductions Programs targeting<br />

the drivers of de<strong>for</strong>estation and <strong>for</strong>est degradation.<br />

18<br />

As pointed out be<strong>for</strong>e, there are high expectations<br />

concerning the positive incentives that could<br />

come from REDD, especially in countries that<br />

see REDD as the only profitable way to enter<br />

the “carbon market”. Some caution is needed,<br />

however, since, even if REDD becomes eligible<br />

under the <strong>CDM</strong> in the post-2012 regime (and<br />

nowadays there is no guarantee that this will<br />

happen), the same constraints that apply to A/R<br />

(e.g. temporary credits) could apply to REDD.<br />

As a result, the demand <strong>for</strong> REDD credits could<br />

be extremely limited, with no effective result in<br />

reducing de<strong>for</strong>estation and no effective payments.<br />

In this sense, discussing the inclusion of REDD<br />

in the <strong>CDM</strong> without solving the problem of nonpermanence<br />

seems irrelevant.<br />

Besides the results of the negotiation<br />

process, there are many challenges<br />

that countries must overcome<br />

in order to achieve REDD:<br />

1. Coordination: because of the complexity of<br />

REDD, many and different actors must be<br />

involved in the different phases. All countries<br />

find coordination among all these different<br />

actors to be one of the biggest challenges;<br />

16 http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2005/cop11/eng/misc01.pdf<br />

17 http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2007/cop13/eng/06a01.<br />

pdf#page=8<br />

18 http://carbonfinance.org/fcpfhttp://carbonfinance.org/fcpf http://<br />

carbonfinance.org/fcpf<br />

Is there a role or even a future in the post-2012 regime?<br />

181<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


2. International leakage: in certain situations,<br />

there is a large potential of leakage over<br />

countries’ borders;<br />

3. Opportunity costs: because of the characteristics<br />

of some of the main drivers <strong>for</strong><br />

de<strong>for</strong>estation and degradation, some opportunity<br />

costs could be very difficult to<br />

determine and to compete with them. In<br />

this case, countries could combine carbon<br />

revenues with other financial resources<br />

(e.g. over-pricing due to agriculture certification)<br />

and have a close dialogue with the<br />

private sector;<br />

4. Institutional arrangements <strong>for</strong> de<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

and degradation: some drivers of de<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

and/or degradation have such complex,<br />

articulated and strong institutional<br />

arrangements (based on a triangular division<br />

of actors) that REDD will demand deep<br />

and painful modifications going far beyond<br />

“payments <strong>for</strong> environmental service”. This<br />

will be especially the case if these payments<br />

are intended to benefit primarily communities<br />

and do not benefit the intermediary<br />

actors present at the institutional arrangements.<br />

These intermediary actors could be<br />

those that will manipulate the communities,<br />

but they will also be used by the top<br />

actors to maintain the status quo;<br />

At the same time, there are many<br />

opportunities that countries could<br />

explore in achieving REDD:<br />

1. Sharing: exchanging in<strong>for</strong>mation and<br />

knowledge between all countries and relevant<br />

organizations and stakeholders. This<br />

could include a web plat<strong>for</strong>m, seminars and<br />

workshops, peer-to-peer meetings, reports<br />

and publications, etc.<br />

2. Non-<strong>for</strong>est approach: because of the characteristics<br />

of some of the main drivers <strong>for</strong><br />

de<strong>for</strong>estation and degradation, the main<br />

potential solutions could lie outside the<br />

<strong>for</strong>est sector. This imposes great challenges,<br />

since the opportunity costs could be<br />

much higher, and coordination with non<strong>for</strong>est<br />

organizations and/or non-<strong>for</strong>est governmental<br />

bodies more complex;<br />

3. Reducing emissions beyond REDD: some of the<br />

main opportunities <strong>for</strong> particular countries<br />

could be outside reducing de<strong>for</strong>estation<br />

and/or degradation (e.g. conversation<br />

and enhancement of carbon stocks);<br />

4. Regional approach: this is definitely something<br />

to explore, taking into consideration<br />

not only the potential benefits, but also the<br />

technical and political consequences.<br />

Conclusions<br />

There is definitely a mandate and a need to<br />

revise the current modalities and procedures<br />

<strong>for</strong> LULUCF project activities under the <strong>CDM</strong>. It<br />

is not clear whether Parties have the “political<br />

will” to do this at the level necessary to produce<br />

concrete and consistent results. Political will is<br />

the main element necessary to decide what kind<br />

of modifications will be applied to A/R and REDD<br />

in the post-2012 climate-change regime.<br />

Un<strong>for</strong>tunately there are not many LULUCF<br />

activities that can benefit from the “learning by<br />

doing” approach. In the non-A/R context, many<br />

of the revisions <strong>for</strong> the post-2012 regime could<br />

be based on concrete experience and cases.<br />

Besides this limitation, there is no reason to give<br />

up on <strong>for</strong>estry project activities in the post-2012<br />

regime. It is unnecessary to explain that reducing<br />

emissions from LULUCF is an important part<br />

of the achievement of the UNFCCC objective.<br />

182<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


Also, it is not necessary to choose between A/R<br />

and REDD. In fact, in some cases they must be<br />

implemented together. They could also have<br />

different sources of financing: A/R through<br />

carbon credits and REDD through funds.<br />

One common element between A/R and REDD<br />

is the treatment of non-permanence. If the<br />

temporary credits solution remains in the post-<br />

2012 regime and will also be applied to REDD<br />

credits, then probably the demand <strong>for</strong> LULUCF<br />

<strong>CDM</strong> project activities will remain extremely<br />

low, being incapable of raising the amount of<br />

financial resources needed to make LULUCF a<br />

real contribution to climate-change mitigation.<br />

The main focus of the discussion should be to find<br />

alternative ways to deal with the non-permanence<br />

issue. Without an alternative approach, inclusion<br />

of REDD in the <strong>CDM</strong> could become irrelevant.<br />

Marcelo Theoto Rocha is a researcher in applied economics<br />

at University of Sao Paulo (CEPEA – ESALQ/USP)<br />

and member of the Af<strong>for</strong>estation/Re<strong>for</strong>estation Working<br />

Group of the <strong>CDM</strong> Executive Board, the Brazilian Delegation<br />

at UNFCCC, and the World Bank Forest Carbon<br />

Partnership Facility (FCPF) Technical Advisory Panel (TAP).<br />

Contact: matrocha@terra.com.br<br />

Because of the complexity of the problem of<br />

climate change, <strong>including</strong> the negotiation process,<br />

possible improvements in the A/R modalities and<br />

procedures, and especially decisions concerning<br />

REDD, cannot be treated in isolation. They will<br />

influence and be influenced by other items of<br />

the negotiation agenda.<br />

Adopting an analogy made by an expert on the<br />

carbon market in the last Carbon Expo regarding<br />

the actual stage of non-A/R <strong>CDM</strong> project<br />

activities: “The low hanging fruits are gone, we<br />

need to start planting <strong>new</strong> fruit trees”. In the<br />

case of the <strong>for</strong>estry projects, it is not possible<br />

to say that until now almost no fruit has been<br />

collected because the decisions taken in the past<br />

have created a very low demand <strong>for</strong> this kind of<br />

fruit. For the post-2012 regime, it is necessary to<br />

make the “<strong>for</strong>estry fruit” more attractive in order<br />

to harvest some of these fruits and in fact plant<br />

some trees.<br />

Is there a role or even a future in the post-2012 regime?<br />

183<br />

CD4<strong>CDM</strong>


The annual CD4<strong>CDM</strong> Perspectives Series features a topic of pivotal importance<br />

to the global carbon market. The series seeks to communicate the diverse<br />

insights and visions of leading actors in the carbon market to better in<strong>for</strong>m the<br />

decisions of professionals and policymakers in developing countries. The second theme<br />

of the series focuses on how the <strong>CDM</strong> can be re<strong>for</strong>med in a post-2012 climate regime,<br />

<strong>including</strong> <strong>new</strong> mechanism <strong>for</strong> sustainable development. Seventeen contributors from<br />

the private sector, Designated National Authorities, the Executive Board, research,<br />

and development agencies present their perspective on meeting challenges such as the<br />

unequal regional distribution of <strong>CDM</strong> projects, concerns about environmental integrity<br />

and technology transfer, complex governance procedures, and questions about the<br />

<strong>CDM</strong>’s contribution to sustainable development. The <strong>new</strong> ideas and solutions to these<br />

challenges proposed by the authors in this edition of Perspectives have<br />

been solicited to help professionals and policy makers make the best<br />

decisions in the lead-up to COP 15 in Copenhagen and beyond.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!