05.11.2014 Views

Indigenous Practices for Soil and Water Conservation - Agropedia

Indigenous Practices for Soil and Water Conservation - Agropedia

Indigenous Practices for Soil and Water Conservation - Agropedia

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

4. A major ef<strong>for</strong>t is required to develop strong sanghams. NGOs can help in<br />

this regard. This is an important prerequisite to developing an efficient<br />

system <strong>for</strong> financing SWC investments.<br />

5. Farmers in SWC programs should be contracted to work on their own l<strong>and</strong><br />

in order to reduce costs <strong>and</strong> improve per<strong>for</strong>mance. They should be paid by<br />

the job, not the hour or day, in order to reduce costs. Where in<strong>for</strong>mation <strong>and</strong><br />

motivation are constraints to adoption, these should be provided to farmers<br />

by state watershed authorities <strong>and</strong> NGOs.<br />

6. Subsidies should be offered only when net social returns to soil conservation<br />

exceed net private returns. This should not be assumed to be the case;<br />

research is needed to examine the circumstances under which it is so.<br />

7. Likewise, subsidies should not significantly replace private investment, but<br />

should be designed to encourage maximum adoption at minimum cost. Thorough<br />

investigation of private practices is needed to ensure that government<br />

programs do not pay <strong>for</strong> investments that would in any case be made<br />

privately. NGO programs can study the extent to which farmers are willing<br />

to contribute.<br />

8. Cost-effectiveness, high adoption, <strong>and</strong> equity can best be achieved through<br />

a subsidy that allots more funds to poorer farmers. This could be done with<br />

a flat rate subsidy that allots funds per family rather than per acre. Alternatively,<br />

a sliding scale with a declining subsidy per acre, reaching zero<br />

after five acres, might prove more effective. Small-holder farmers would<br />

thus receive a higher subsidy per acre than large-scale farmers, who may be<br />

able to af<strong>for</strong>d to spend more. (While l<strong>and</strong>holding size is not the best indicator<br />

of willingness or ability to pay <strong>for</strong> soil conservation measures, it may be<br />

the most practical proxy. NGOs can experiment to achieve more accurate<br />

targetting).<br />

9. In principle, subsidies should be given at a fixed rate rather than as a<br />

percentage of total costs, in order to encourage less expensive technologies.<br />

NGO programs should experiment with this <strong>and</strong> other innovative subsidy<br />

schemes to determine the best ones.<br />

I I I .<br />

F l e x i b l e S W C P r o g r a m s<br />

1. <strong>Water</strong>shed officials must recognize that farmers are their primary clients.<br />

2. <strong>Water</strong>shed plans must be based on surveys carried out through a participatory<br />

approach with local farmers. For this purpose the village community<br />

should be grouped into smaller homogeneous units so that their different<br />

needs <strong>and</strong> perspectives can be understood <strong>and</strong> addressed.<br />

3. <strong>Indigenous</strong> SWC practices should be incorporated in the watershed plan.<br />

Further, indigenous knowledge from different agroclimatic zones must be<br />

documented <strong>and</strong> circulated to implementing agencies to create greater<br />

awareness <strong>and</strong> appreciation.<br />

4. <strong>Water</strong>shed works should be executed by beneficiaries under the auspices of<br />

49

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!