31.01.2015 Views

Income Diversification and Poverty Income Diversification and Poverty

Income Diversification and Poverty Income Diversification and Poverty

Income Diversification and Poverty Income Diversification and Poverty

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong><br />

in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s of Vietnam<br />

Patterns, trends, <strong>and</strong> policy implications<br />

IFPRI ®<br />

INTERNATIONAL FOOD POLICY<br />

RESEARCH INSTITUTE<br />

sustainable solutions for ending hunger <strong>and</strong> poverty<br />

JAPAN BANK FOR<br />

INTERNATIONAL<br />

COOPERATION


INCOME DIVERSIFICATION AND POVERTY<br />

IN THE NORTHERN UPLANDS OF VIETNAM<br />

Prepared by:<br />

Markets, Trade, <strong>and</strong> Institutions Division<br />

International Food Policy Research Institute<br />

Washington, D.C. USA<br />

Prepared for:<br />

Social Development Division<br />

Sector Strategy Development Department<br />

Japan Bank for International Cooperation<br />

Tokyo, Japan<br />

10 July 2003


Contact information:<br />

Nicholas Minot / International Food Policy Research Institute / 2033 K St. NW / Washington, D.C.<br />

20006 USA / Phone: +1 202 862-5600 / Fax: +1 202 467-4439 / Email: n.minot@cgiar.org<br />

Shigeru Yamamura/ Japan Bank for International Cooperation/ 4-1, Otemachi 1-Chome, Chiyoda-ku,<br />

Tokyo 100-8144, Japan/ Phone: +81-3-5218-9691/ Fax: +81-3-5218-9084/<br />

Email: s-yamamura@jbic.go.jp<br />

Printed by Tran Phu Co Ltd, Hanoi.<br />

Copyright © 2003 International Food Policy Research Institute <strong>and</strong> Japan Bank for International<br />

Cooperation. All rights reserved.<br />

Page ii


ABBREVIATIONS<br />

CH<br />

CIEM<br />

DARD<br />

DOLISA<br />

GDLA<br />

GDP<br />

GIS<br />

GSO<br />

IFPRI<br />

JBIC<br />

MARD<br />

MOLISA<br />

MRD<br />

NCC<br />

NIAPP<br />

NU<br />

QSAID<br />

RRD<br />

SAM<br />

SCC<br />

SDC<br />

SE<br />

SID<br />

SIDA<br />

SW<br />

UNDP<br />

VHLSS<br />

VLSS<br />

VND<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Central Institute for Economic Management<br />

Department of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development<br />

Department of Labor, Invalids, <strong>and</strong> Social Affairs<br />

General Department for L<strong>and</strong> Administration<br />

Gross domestic product<br />

Geographic Information Systems<br />

General Statistics Office<br />

International Food Policy Research Institute<br />

Japan Bank for International Cooperation<br />

Ministry of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development<br />

Ministry of Labor, Invalids, <strong>and</strong> Social Affairs<br />

Mekong River Delta<br />

North Central Coast<br />

National Institute for Agricultural Planning <strong>and</strong> Projection<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s (including the Northeast <strong>and</strong> Northwest)<br />

Qualitative Social Assessment of <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

Red River Delta<br />

Social Accounting Matrix<br />

South Central Coast<br />

Swiss Agency for Development <strong>and</strong> Cooperation<br />

Southeast (also called the Northeast South)<br />

Simpson Index of Diversity<br />

Swedish International Development Agency<br />

Shannon-Weaver Index of Diversity<br />

United Nations Development Programme<br />

Vietnam Household Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey<br />

Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey<br />

Vietnamese dong<br />

Page iii


Page iv


ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS<br />

The preparation of this report would not have been possible without the contributions of a large<br />

number of Vietnamese <strong>and</strong> international collaborators. The funding for the project was provided by<br />

the Japan Bank for International Cooperation (JBIC). Mr. Shigeru Yamamura (JBIC/Tokyo) provided<br />

a firm but helpful h<strong>and</strong> in guiding the design <strong>and</strong> implementation of the project to ensure that the final<br />

product would be useful to both the Government of Vietnam <strong>and</strong> the international community in<br />

Vietnam. Mr. T. Shimokawa, Mr. Y. Hayakawa, <strong>and</strong> Ms. Van Anh, all from the Hanoi office of<br />

JBIC, provided logistical support <strong>and</strong> useful feedback. In addition, funding from the Swiss Agency<br />

for Development <strong>and</strong> Cooperation (SDC) made possible the participation of Michael Epprecht in the<br />

project, whose numerous contributions are described below.<br />

The project was implemented in collaboration with the Ministry of Labor, Invalids, <strong>and</strong> Social Affairs<br />

(MOLISA). Dr. Nguyen Hai Huu, Director of the Department of Social Protection at MOLISA<br />

provided useful suggestions <strong>and</strong> advice regarding the design of the Qualitative Social Assessment of<br />

<strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> (QSAID) <strong>and</strong> supplied valuable logistical support to our two teams of field<br />

researchers. This support allowed them to visit a large number of provincial, district, <strong>and</strong> commune<br />

officials in eight provinces over the course of the three-months of field work. Dr. Huu also provided<br />

constructive feedback on an earlier draft of the report. Finally, he <strong>and</strong> his staff helped organize the<br />

workshops in Thai Nguyen <strong>and</strong> Hanoi to present the results of the study.<br />

Mr. Michael Epprecht, IFPRI’s Junior Professional Officer based in Hanoi with funding from SDC,<br />

was involved in almost every phase of the project, playing the roles of survey specialist, enumerator<br />

trainer, project manager, field work supervisor, <strong>and</strong> research analyst. He also gathered <strong>and</strong> analyzed<br />

GIS data <strong>and</strong> prepared all the maps that appear in the report. Dr. John Dennis, an independent<br />

consultant contracted by IFPRI, assisted in the design, management, <strong>and</strong> interpretation of the QSAID<br />

field work.<br />

Ms. Le Thi Phi Van, the administrative coordinator for the IFPRI office in Hanoi (seconded from the<br />

Institute for Agricultural Economics), provided valuable logistical support for the QSAID, serving as<br />

accountant, office manager, research assistant, document translator, <strong>and</strong> field interpreter.<br />

The processing <strong>and</strong> analyzing the 1993, 1998, <strong>and</strong> 2002 national household surveys was a major task,<br />

a task which would not have been possible without the tireless effort of IFPRI research analyst Ms.<br />

Reno Dewina.<br />

Most of the field work for the QSAID was conducted by two teams, each consisting of three local<br />

researchers. The team leaders were Ms. Tran Thi Tram Anh ( Research Institute for Market & Price)<br />

<strong>and</strong> Dr. Dao Trong Hung (Institute of Ecology <strong>and</strong> Biological Resources). They were supported by<br />

Ms Ta Thi Tham (Forestry University), Mr. Le Quang Trung (Forest Science Institute), Mr. Nguyen<br />

Anh Phong (National Institute for Agricultural Planning <strong>and</strong> Projection), <strong>and</strong> Mr. Nguyen Ngoc<br />

Quang (Forest Science Institute). Mr Le Dong Phuong also played a key role as interpreter, translator,<br />

<strong>and</strong> facilitator before <strong>and</strong> during the field work. The QSAID required traveling to eight provincial<br />

capitals, 16 district headquarters, 16 commune centers, 32 rural villages, <strong>and</strong> over 300 households to<br />

conduct the interviews. This task was completed on time <strong>and</strong> with good results, thanks to the<br />

resourcefulness, persistence, <strong>and</strong> dedication of the teams.<br />

The development <strong>and</strong> analysis of the social accounting matrix for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region,<br />

including the preparation of Chapter 7, was carried out by Dr. David Rol<strong>and</strong>-Holst (Mills College,<br />

Page v


USA), with assistance from Dr. Finn Tarp (University of Copenhagen, Denmark), <strong>and</strong> in collaboration<br />

with researchers the Central Institute for Economic Management (CIEM) in Hanoi.<br />

Finally, we would like to thank various people who have offered comments <strong>and</strong> suggestions on earlier<br />

drafts of the report, including Mr. S. Yamamura (JBIC), Dr. Nguyen Hai Huu (Director of the<br />

Department of Social Protection, MOLISA), Dr. Dang Kim Son (Director of the Information Center<br />

for Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development, MARD), Dr. Nguyen Phong (Director of Social <strong>and</strong><br />

Environmental Statistics, GSO) Mr. Peter Sturm (GTZ advisor at CIEM), Dr. Ngo Huy Liem (GTZ<br />

advisor to MOLISA), <strong>and</strong> participants at workshops in Thai Nguyen (3 June 2003), Hanoi (4 June<br />

2003), <strong>and</strong> at the Japan Bank for International Cooperation in Tokyo (9 June 2003).<br />

It is hoped that the value of the results will justify all the hard work put into the field work, analysis,<br />

<strong>and</strong> report preparation.<br />

Dr. Nicholas Minot<br />

Research Fellow <strong>and</strong> Project Leader<br />

International Food Policy Research Institute<br />

n.minot@cgiar.org<br />

10 July 2003<br />

.<br />

Page vi


TABLE OF CONTENTS<br />

Abbreviations ................................................................................................................................... iii<br />

Acknowledgements .......................................................................................................................... .v<br />

Chapter 1: Introduction ................................................................................................................. .1<br />

1.1 Introduction……………………………………………………………………….. 1<br />

1.2 Objectives……………………………………………………………………….. .. 2<br />

1.3 Methods <strong>and</strong> activities ……………………………………………………………. 3<br />

1.3.1 Analysis of GSO statistics………………………………………………... 4<br />

1.3.2 Analysis of household survey data……………………………………….. 4<br />

1.3.3 Qualitative Social Assessment of <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong>……………….. 5<br />

1.3.4 Construction <strong>and</strong> analysis of social accounting matrix…………………… 5<br />

1.4 Organization of the report…………………………………………………………. 6<br />

Chapter 2: Background on diversification <strong>and</strong> the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s………………………. 9<br />

2.1 Background on income diversification……………………………………………. 9<br />

2.1.1 Definitions of diversification……………………………………………... 9<br />

2.1.2 Determinants of diversification………………………………………… 10<br />

2.1.3 Effects of diversification………………………………………………….12<br />

2.1.4 International patterns in diversification…………………………………...12<br />

2.2 Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s……………………………………………..17<br />

2.2.1 Geography……………………………………………………………….. 18<br />

2.2.2 Population…………………………………………………………………18<br />

2.2.3 L<strong>and</strong> use <strong>and</strong> agriculture…………………………………………………. 22<br />

2.2.4 <strong>Income</strong> <strong>and</strong> poverty……………………………………………………….30<br />

2.2.5 <strong>Income</strong> diversification…………………………………………………….32<br />

2.3 Summary………………………………………………………………………….. 37<br />

Chapter 3: Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification:<br />

Analysis of three national household surveys…………………………………………………… 39<br />

3.1 Introduction………………………………………………………………………..39<br />

3.2 Data <strong>and</strong> methods………………………………………………………………….40<br />

3.2.1 Data………………………………………………………………………. 40<br />

3.2.2 Calculation of income……………………………………………………. 42<br />

3.2.3 Measurement of income diversification…………………………………. 43<br />

3.2.4 Measuring the contribution of diversification to income growth……….. 45<br />

3.3 Changes in st<strong>and</strong>ard of living in rural areas……………………………………… 47<br />

3.4 Source of income in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s………………………………………. 50<br />

3.5 <strong>Diversification</strong> as multiple sources of income …………………………………… 54<br />

3.5.1 Diversity in income sources………………………………………………54<br />

3.5.2 Diversity in crop production…………………………………………….. 57<br />

3.6 <strong>Diversification</strong> as commercialization…………………………………………….. 58<br />

3.7 <strong>Diversification</strong> as participation in high-value activities………………………….. 61<br />

3.7.1 Participation in high-value activities…………………………………….. 62<br />

3.7.2 Participation in high-value crop production……………………………... 63<br />

3.8 Contribution of diversification to rural income growth………………………….. 66<br />

3.8.1 Contribution of income diversification …………………………………. 67<br />

3.8.2 Contribution of crop diversification………………………………………74<br />

3.9 Determinants of income diversification………………………………………….. 79<br />

3.10 Summary………………………………………………………………………….. 85<br />

Page vii


Chapter 4. Analysis of food dem<strong>and</strong>…………………………………………………………… 87<br />

4.1 Introduction………………………………………………………………………..87<br />

4.2 Method……………………………………………………………………………. 87<br />

4.3 Results……………………………………………………………………………..89<br />

Chapter 5. <strong>Income</strong> diversification from the farmers’ perspectives…………………………… 95<br />

5.1 Methods……………………………………………………………………………95<br />

5.1.1 Questionnaire…………………………………………………………….. 95<br />

5.1.2 Sampling <strong>and</strong> data collection…………………………………………….. 96<br />

5.1.3 Measures of income <strong>and</strong> accessibility…………………………………….97<br />

5.2 General characteristics…………………………………………………………… 99<br />

5.2.1 Household size <strong>and</strong> composition……………………………………….. 100<br />

5.2.2 Housing………………………………………………………………… 102<br />

5.2.3 Assets…………………………………………………………………… 102<br />

5.3 Food security <strong>and</strong> income……………………………………………………….. 104<br />

5.3.1 Perceived level of food security <strong>and</strong> income…………………………... 104<br />

5.3.2 Perceived changes in income…………………………………………... 106<br />

5.3.3 Perceived reasons for changes in income……………………………….107<br />

5.4 Sources of income………………………………………………………………..110<br />

5.4.1 Current income sources………………………………………………… 110<br />

5.4.2 Changes in income sources over time………………………………….. 112<br />

5.5 Experiences with diversification…………………………………………………116<br />

5.5.1 Successful experiences with diversification…………………………… 116<br />

5.5.2 Unsuccessful experiences with diversification………………………… 118<br />

5.5.3 Perceptions regarding diversification……………………………………119<br />

5.6 Role of traders <strong>and</strong> processors……………………………………………………123<br />

5.7 Role of government………………………………………………………………126<br />

5.8 Case studies………………………………………………………………………129<br />

5.9 Summary………………………………………………………………………… 131<br />

Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government………………………. 133<br />

6.1 Methods…………………………………………………………………………. 133<br />

6.2 Patterns of diversification ……………………………………………………… 135<br />

6.3 Role of government in promoting diversification……………………………… 139<br />

6.4 Role of traders in diversification………………………………………………... 142<br />

6.5 Role of state-owned enterprises………………………………………………… 143<br />

6.6 Perceived constraints on diversification………………………………………… 144<br />

6.6.1 Unfavorable production conditions…………………………………….. 144<br />

6.6.2 Low level of education <strong>and</strong> training……………………………………. 144<br />

6.6.3 Population pressure on l<strong>and</strong> resources…………………………………. 144<br />

6.6.4 Lack of credit…………………………………………………………… 145<br />

6.6.5 Poor infrastructure……………………………………………………….145<br />

6.6.6 Inappropriate development projects……………………………………. 145<br />

6.6.7 Lack of information needed for production ……………………………. 146<br />

6.6.8 Marketing problems……………………………………………………. 146<br />

6.6.9 Weak extension service………………………………………………….147<br />

6.7 Summary………………………………………………………………………… 147<br />

Page viii


Chapter 7. A social accounting analysis of economic linkages <strong>and</strong> diversification …………149<br />

7.1 Introduction………………………………………………………………………149<br />

7.2 SAM analysis…………………………………………………………………… 149<br />

7.2.1 Overview……………………………………………………………….. 149<br />

7.2.2 Estimation of macro SAMs for the provinces………………………….. 150<br />

7.2.3 Data resources for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s macro SAM…………………. 154<br />

7.2.4 Estimation of the microeconomic SAM for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s…….. 157<br />

7.3 Structure of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s economy……………………………………. 158<br />

7.3.1 Supply…………………………………………………………………... 158<br />

7.3.2 Dem<strong>and</strong>…………………………………………………………………. 160<br />

7.3.3 Value added…………………………………………………………….. 164<br />

7.3.4 Factor income……………………………………………………………165<br />

7.4 Linkages between the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> other regions…………………….. 170<br />

7.4.1 Estimating the two-region micro SAM………………………………….170<br />

7.4.2 Decomposition of income-expenditure linkages……………………….. 172<br />

7.5 Summary………………………………………………………………………… 175<br />

Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions ……………………………………………………….. 179<br />

8.1 Summary………………………………………………………………………… 179<br />

8.1.1 Introduction…………………………………………………………….. 179<br />

8.1.2 Background on diversification <strong>and</strong> the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s………………179<br />

8.1.3 Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification…………………………………… 181<br />

8.1.4 Analysis of food dem<strong>and</strong> patterns……………………………………… 182<br />

8.1.5 <strong>Income</strong> diversification from the farmers’ perspective………………….. 183<br />

8.1.6 <strong>Income</strong> diversification from local government’s perspective………….. 185<br />

8.1.7 Social accounting analysis……………………………………………… 186<br />

8.2 Conclusions <strong>and</strong> implications for policy…………………………………………186<br />

8.2.1 Implications for rural development strategy……………………………. 187<br />

8.2.2 Implications for agricultural research…………………………………... 188<br />

8.2.3 Implications for input subsidies………………………………………… 190<br />

8.2.4 Implications for agricultural extension…………………………………. 191<br />

8.2.5 Implications for public investment………………………………………193<br />

8.2.6 Implications for credit policy……………………………………………194<br />

8.2.7 Implications for livestock development…………………………………195<br />

8.2.8 Implications for promoting non-farm employment………………..…… 196<br />

References...................................................................................................................................... 199<br />

Glossary ......................................................................................................................................... 205<br />

Appendix A. Results of the analysis of the determinants of agricultural supply ................... 211<br />

Appendix B. Interview Guidelines for Farm Households ........................................................ 219<br />

Appendix C. Interview Guidelines for Provincial Authorities................................................. 233<br />

Appendix D. Constructing an index of st<strong>and</strong>ard of living for the QSAID<br />

Household Survey ................................................................................................. 239<br />

Appendix E. Details of the Macro SAM construction .............................................................. 245<br />

Page ix


CHAPTER ONE<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

1.1 Introduction<br />

In many ways, Vietnam is in an enviable position among developing countries. Since the<br />

mid-1990s, it has enjoyed macro-economic stability <strong>and</strong> sustained high rates of economic growth.<br />

According to the Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Surveys, the incidence of poverty fell from 58 percent in<br />

1993 to 37 percent in 1998 (Joint Working Group, 2000). Vietnam has benefited from trade<br />

liberalization <strong>and</strong> the rapid growth of the region, but was able to avoid the worst effects of the 1997-<br />

98 Asian financial crisis. From a situation of chronic rice shortages in the 1980s, it has transformed<br />

itself into one of the three largest rice exporters in the world. Similarly, it has dramatically exp<strong>and</strong>ed<br />

exports of coffee, seafood, <strong>and</strong> fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables.<br />

At the same time, Vietnam faces serious development challenges. In spite of the rapid pace of<br />

economic growth, Vietnam remains among the 30 poorest countries in the world 1 . Furthermore, there<br />

is concern that the process of market liberalization, while unleashing the economic potential of the<br />

country, may also have exacerbated the disparities between urban <strong>and</strong> rural areas, between north <strong>and</strong><br />

south, <strong>and</strong> between delta regions <strong>and</strong> upl<strong>and</strong> regions.<br />

<strong>Poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> under-employment are particularly serious problems in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong><br />

region. According to a recent study, the ten poorest provinces of Vietnam are in this region, with<br />

poverty rates ranging from 55 to 78 percent (Minot <strong>and</strong> Baulch, 2002). In addition to the high<br />

incidence of poverty, this region is characterized by:<br />

• Rugged upl<strong>and</strong> terrain<br />

• Poor infrastructure<br />

• A large ethnic minority population<br />

• Low population density <strong>and</strong> low levels of urbanization<br />

• Importance of the agricultural sector.<br />

Although economic growth will not necessarily solve all the problems of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, there<br />

is little doubt that sustained <strong>and</strong> widespread growth in household incomes is a necessary component<br />

of any successful development strategy for the region.<br />

<strong>Income</strong> growth in an agricultural economy can come from various sources. First, we can<br />

distinguish between growth in crop income, non-crop agricultural income (livestock, fisheries, <strong>and</strong><br />

forestry), <strong>and</strong> non-agricultural income. Given that semi-subsistence farmers often focus on the<br />

1<br />

This is based on per capita gross national product using market exchange rates. If the exchange rates<br />

are adjusted to reflect purchasing power parity, Vietnam’s relative position improves, but it is still ranked 164<br />

out of 210 countries (World Bank, 2000: 231).<br />

Page 1


Chapter 1. Introduction<br />

production of staple food crops, the switch to non-crop activities is often referred to as income<br />

diversification. The growth in crop income can be further broken down into five components.<br />

• Area expansion. This may be the result of clearing new l<strong>and</strong>s, rehabilitating degraded<br />

l<strong>and</strong>, or reducing fallow periods.<br />

• Increasing cropping intensity. The number of harvests per year can be increased by<br />

adopting varieties or crops with shorter growing cycles or by improving water control on<br />

the off-season.<br />

• Yield increases. Higher yields, defined as the output per sown area, are associated with<br />

improved seed, greater or more effective use of modern inputs, improved water control,<br />

<strong>and</strong>/or better cultivation methods.<br />

• Higher agricultural prices. These may be caused by market liberalization, improved<br />

transport infrastructure, or better coordination between farmers <strong>and</strong> buyers.<br />

• Crop diversification. Even if prices, cropping yields, intensity, <strong>and</strong> area remain constant,<br />

farmers can increase their income by reallocating l<strong>and</strong> from low-value crops (typically<br />

staple food crops) to higher-value crops (typically commercial crops).<br />

All of these factors probably play some role in the growth of rural income, but the relative<br />

importance of each factor varies across households depending on agro-ecological conditions, market<br />

access, <strong>and</strong> household characteristics. The importance of each factor changes over time as well.<br />

Rising population density is causing the importance of area expansion to decline <strong>and</strong> that of yield<br />

improvement to increase. In addition, rising domestic income is leading to changes in the diet, which,<br />

combined with international trade, contribute to crop diversification away from food production<br />

toward commercial crop production. In spite of the importance of these trends, there is little<br />

information on the contribution of each factor to the growth of rural incomes in Vietnam.<br />

A premise of this study is that income diversification is an important avenue for income<br />

growth among rural households. A corollary is that poverty reduction depends on the ability of small<br />

farmers to participate in the general process of crop diversification <strong>and</strong> the shift toward non-farm<br />

activities. Thus, it is important to more fully underst<strong>and</strong> the patterns of diversification <strong>and</strong> non-farm<br />

activities in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region, the constraints that prevent farmers from adopting these<br />

strategies to raise their incomes, <strong>and</strong> the options available to the government <strong>and</strong> international<br />

organizations for relieving these constraints.<br />

1.2 Objectives<br />

In light of this background, this study examines income diversification in the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong> region of Vietnam, its contribution to poverty reduction, <strong>and</strong> the constraints to further<br />

diversification. More specifically, the objectives of this project are:<br />

• To describe the patterns of crop diversification <strong>and</strong> non-farm activities at the household<br />

level,<br />

• To compare the extent <strong>and</strong> patterns of diversification in 1993, 1998, <strong>and</strong> 2002,<br />

• To estimate the relative importance of various sources of rural income growth in the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region of Vietnam: yield increases, crop price increases, diversification<br />

Page 2


Chapter 1. Introduction<br />

into high-value crops, growth in non-crop agricultural activities, <strong>and</strong> growth in non-farm<br />

activities.<br />

• To estimate the relative importance of income diversification <strong>and</strong> other sources of income<br />

growth in reducing rural poverty,<br />

• To compare different types of income diversification in terms of their multiplier effects,<br />

inter-sectoral linkages, <strong>and</strong> contribution to poverty reduction,<br />

• To examine the constraints that farmers in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region face in<br />

diversifying into high-value commodities <strong>and</strong> non-farm activities,<br />

• To identify policy options for facilitating the income diversification <strong>and</strong> poverty reduction<br />

in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region.<br />

While providing information on the patterns of rural income growth in Vietnam, the study<br />

also demonstrates <strong>and</strong> tests a methodology for decomposing income growth which could be applied in<br />

other countries.<br />

1.3 Methods <strong>and</strong> activities<br />

This study uses four approaches to gathering information about diversification <strong>and</strong> poverty in<br />

the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s of Vietnam:<br />

• Analysis of economic <strong>and</strong> agricultural trends at the provincial level using data from the<br />

General Statistics Office (GSO).<br />

• Analysis <strong>and</strong> comparison of three surveys: the 1992-93 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards<br />

Survey, the 1997-98 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey, <strong>and</strong> the 2002 Vietnam Household<br />

Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey.<br />

• Implementation of a Qualitative Social Assessment of <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> (QSAID) to<br />

gather information on the perceptions of farmers, local officials, <strong>and</strong> traders regarding the<br />

constraints to income diversification in selected communes of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong><br />

region.<br />

• Construction <strong>and</strong> analysis of a social accounting matrix (SAM) to describe the economy<br />

of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region, with particular emphasis on the inter-sectoral implications<br />

of income diversification.<br />

Although addressing the same issues, these four approaches complement each other. By<br />

examining GSO statistics, we can better underst<strong>and</strong> broad trends in the economy <strong>and</strong> it highlights the<br />

diversity across provinces within the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. The analysis of the three household surveys<br />

provides information on the historical patterns of income diversification <strong>and</strong> poverty reduction, but<br />

does not explain the constraints to diversification or describe the macro-economic context. The<br />

QSAID sheds light on the constraints to diversification <strong>and</strong> the perceptions of farmers <strong>and</strong> local<br />

officials, but does not generate statistically representative results. And the SAM analysis highlights<br />

the macro-economic context <strong>and</strong> inter-sectoral linkages of diversification, but will not highlight policy<br />

constraints, nor describe historical patterns. Each approach is described in more detail below.<br />

Page 3


Chapter 1. Introduction<br />

1.3.1 Analysis of GSO statistics<br />

The General Statistics Office (GSO) publishes a wide variety of statistics at the provincial<br />

level, including many economic <strong>and</strong> agricultural indicators. In this study, we examine trends over the<br />

five-year period 1995-2000. Among the variables we consider are the share of gross domestic<br />

product from agriculture, the share of total area cropped, the allocation of crop l<strong>and</strong> among different<br />

crops, rice production per capita, <strong>and</strong> the value of agricultural output per hectare of agricultural l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Unlike the analysis of household survey data <strong>and</strong> the Qualitative Social Assessment of <strong>Income</strong><br />

<strong>Diversification</strong>, this analysis gives us some perspective on the differences across provinces within the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

1.3.2 Analysis of household survey data<br />

Three high-quality household surveys are available for Vietnam. The 1992-93 <strong>and</strong> 1997-98<br />

Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Surveys are suitable for the analysis of rural income diversification in<br />

several respects:<br />

• The VLSS surveys are comprehensive enough to allow calculation of various components<br />

of income. The questionnaires are more than 100 pages long.<br />

• They are based on relatively large samples of 4800 <strong>and</strong> 6000 households, respectively,<br />

allowing us to disaggregate the results for different regions <strong>and</strong> household categories.<br />

• They use similar questionnaires <strong>and</strong> samples so the results are comparable. In fact, there<br />

is some overlap in the samples.<br />

The 2002 Vietnam Household Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey (VHLSS) is somewhat different in<br />

that it has a shorter questionnaire (about 43 pages) but a much larger sample. The survey has a<br />

sample of about 75,000, but we use a sub-sample of about 15,000 households for which expenditure<br />

data are available <strong>and</strong> for which the General Statistics Office has cleaned the data 2 . The VHLSS<br />

questionnaire is similar, but not identical, to the two VLSS questionnaires, so we can compare some<br />

indicators over the three years, but some of the analysis can only be carried out on the two VLSS data<br />

sets.<br />

We define three types of diversification: crop diversification (from low-value to high-value<br />

crops), agricultural diversification (from crop production to livestock <strong>and</strong> fisheries), <strong>and</strong> sectoral<br />

diversification (from agriculture to non-agricultural activities). The process <strong>and</strong> patterns may differ<br />

among these three types of diversification. The study decomposes rural income growth into various<br />

components: yield changes, crop price changes, crop diversification, changes in non-crop agricultural<br />

income, <strong>and</strong> changes in non-farm income. Thus, it is possible to measure the percentage contribution<br />

of diversification to rural income growth over 1993-98 relative to other factors such as yield growth,<br />

area expansion, <strong>and</strong> higher prices.<br />

2<br />

At the time this analysis was carried out, data had been cleaned for about 40,000 households but no<br />

information on expenditure was collected. In the first two rounds of the survey, expenditure data were collected<br />

for about 15,000 households.<br />

Page 4


Chapter 1. Introduction<br />

In addition to the analysis of patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification, the project uses the VLSS<br />

data to estimate two econometric models. First, we estimate the dem<strong>and</strong> for food using the linear<br />

approximation of the Almost Ideal Dem<strong>and</strong> System (LA/AIDS). Symmetry is imposed on the crossprice<br />

terms to ensure that the resulting dem<strong>and</strong> model conforms with dem<strong>and</strong> theory. Second, the<br />

project uses the VLSS data to estimate econometrically the supply of major crops.<br />

1.3.3 Qualitative Social Assessment of <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

In order to develop a more in-depth underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the process of income diversification<br />

<strong>and</strong> the constraints that prevent farmers, particularly poor farmers, from diversifying into high-value<br />

commodities <strong>and</strong> non-farm activities, the project has carried a Qualitative Social Assessment of<br />

<strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> (QSAID). The QSAID consists of a combination of informal qualitative<br />

interviews, semi-structured interviews, <strong>and</strong> structured interviews with farm households <strong>and</strong> local<br />

authorities at the provincial, district, <strong>and</strong> commune levels. Because of the difficulties of carrying out<br />

qualitative research with a large sample, the project focuses on eight provinces, 16 districts, <strong>and</strong> 16<br />

communes in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region.<br />

The QSAID was carried out by two teams of three Vietnamese researchers after a series of<br />

meetings <strong>and</strong> field tests to develop the interview guidelines. The QSAID focuses on three related<br />

questions:<br />

1. What is the current pattern of income diversification In particular, we are interested in<br />

the types of diversification, the proportion of households participating, <strong>and</strong> the types of<br />

household participating in terms of their income, education, location, skills, ethnicity, <strong>and</strong><br />

so on.<br />

2. How has income diversification changed in this commune over the past 5-10 years We<br />

would like to explore the process of diversification over this period <strong>and</strong> identify the key<br />

policies, investments, or structural factors that contributed to this process.<br />

3. What are the constraints to further stimulating rural income diversification in this<br />

commune<br />

Although the sample is relatively small <strong>and</strong> the results must be considered tentative, the QSAID<br />

allows us to address some specific issues related to income diversification that cannot be examined<br />

with household survey data.<br />

1.3.4 Construction <strong>and</strong> analysis of social accounting matrix<br />

The direct impact of income diversification can be studied quantitatively with survey data <strong>and</strong><br />

qualitatively with interviews with key informants. However, at least as important as the direct impact<br />

of income diversification on participating households are the indirect (or multiplier) effects. These<br />

effects can occur through three channels: backward production linkages, forward production linkages,<br />

<strong>and</strong> consumption linkages.<br />

• Backward production linkages refer to the effect of income diversification on the dem<strong>and</strong><br />

for inputs into the production activity, particularly locally-produced inputs. For example,<br />

Page 5


Chapter 1. Introduction<br />

the growth of a fishery industry may result in additional dem<strong>and</strong> for locally produced fish<br />

food, fingerlings, pond construction services, <strong>and</strong> so on.<br />

• Forward production linkages refer to the effect of income diversification on downstream<br />

users of the commodity For example, the same fishery industry development may lead to<br />

new fish drying <strong>and</strong> trading enterprises, generating income for employees <strong>and</strong> owners.<br />

• Consumption linkages refer to the impact of diversification on household income <strong>and</strong>,<br />

indirectly, the dem<strong>and</strong> for goods consumed by those households. For example,<br />

households whose incomes have been increased by aquaculture may increase their<br />

purchases of meat, fruits, <strong>and</strong> vegetables, with indirect effects on producers of these<br />

commodities.<br />

The project constructed a social accounting matrix (SAM) that represents the economy of the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region of Vietnam. The regional SAM has been adapted from a national SAM<br />

constructed by two of the international consultants <strong>and</strong> two of the local consultants included in this<br />

proposal (see Tarp et al, 2001, Tarp et al, 2002a, Tarp et al, 2002b, <strong>and</strong> Tarp <strong>and</strong> Rol<strong>and</strong>-Holst, 2002).<br />

This SAM was calibrated to represent the Vietnamese economy in 1999 <strong>and</strong> has a relatively<br />

disaggregated agricultural sector.<br />

The regional SAM would be used to assess the economy-wide impact of different types of<br />

income diversification. In particular, the SAM analysis includes:<br />

• Documentation of the regional Social Accounting Matrix, including a narrative structural<br />

analysis of the regional economy.<br />

• A study of multiplier linkages between agricultural households <strong>and</strong> domestic <strong>and</strong> external<br />

markets.<br />

• A multiplier study of linkages between agricultural activities (particularly cropping<br />

patterns) <strong>and</strong> income distribution in the region <strong>and</strong> in comparison to the country as a<br />

whole.<br />

• A regional multiplier decomposition analysis of linkages between the north <strong>and</strong> the rest of<br />

the economy.<br />

1.4 Organization of the report<br />

Chapter 2 provides some background on income diversification <strong>and</strong> on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

After a review of some of the definitions <strong>and</strong> determinants of income diversification, the chapter<br />

demonstrates the diversity that exists within the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s by describing differences across<br />

the provinces using demographic, economic, <strong>and</strong> agricultural data.<br />

Chapter 3 describes the patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in income diversification by comparing the results<br />

of the 1992-93 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey (VLSS), the 1997-98 VLSS, <strong>and</strong> the 2002 Vietnam<br />

Household Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey. The data are used to describe the sources of household income<br />

<strong>and</strong> how it varies across different types of households, to measure the contribution of income from<br />

each sector to overall income growth, <strong>and</strong> to estimate the contribution of crop diversification to<br />

growth in crop income.<br />

Chapter 4 carries out an analysis of food dem<strong>and</strong> patterns using the 1997-98 Vietnam Living<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey. The dem<strong>and</strong> for 14 food categories is estimated econometrically using Zellner’s<br />

Page 6


Chapter 1. Introduction<br />

seemingly unrelated regression <strong>and</strong> an approximation of the Almost Ideal Dem<strong>and</strong> System. The<br />

results are used to identify the agricultural commodities whose dem<strong>and</strong> is likely to grow rapidly in<br />

response to rising incomes.<br />

Chapter 5 uses the results from the Qualitative Social Assessment of <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

to explore the experiences <strong>and</strong> perceptions of farmers in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s with regard to the<br />

process of income diversification. This chapter covers changes in income patterns since 1994,<br />

successful <strong>and</strong> unsuccessful attempts to introduce new crops, the catalyzing factors that convinced<br />

them to try new crops, the role of government in the process of diversification, <strong>and</strong> opinions regarding<br />

the most useful government interventions to assist poor rural households.<br />

Chapter 6 continues to explore the results of the QSAID, focusing on the interviews with<br />

local government officials. The interviews collected information on the patterns of diversification by<br />

local farmers, the initiatives by local government to promote new crops, <strong>and</strong> their perceptions<br />

regarding the role of traders, processors, <strong>and</strong> state enterprises.<br />

Chapter 7 presents the social accounting matrix (SAM), developed to simulate the intersectoral<br />

linkages in the economy of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. The SAM is used to explore the indirect<br />

economic impact of shifts in production associated with diversification<br />

And Chapter 8 summarize the results obtained from the various components of the project,<br />

draws some conclusions, <strong>and</strong> identifies some implications for public investment <strong>and</strong> agricultural<br />

policy to facilitate the process of diversification <strong>and</strong> allow small farmers to participate in the process.<br />

Page 7


CHAPTER TWO<br />

BACKGROUND ON DIVERSIFICATION AND THE NORTHERN UPLANDS<br />

This chapter provides a brief review of previous studies of income diversification <strong>and</strong> a<br />

descriptive background of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region. The goal is to provide some international<br />

<strong>and</strong> local context that will assist in the interpretation of the results of this study that are presented in<br />

subsequent chapters.<br />

2.1 Background on income diversification<br />

2.1.1 Definitions of diversification<br />

In the analysis of household income, the term “diversification” has been used to describe<br />

several related but distinct concepts. One definition of diversification, perhaps closest to the original<br />

meaning of the word, refers to an increase in the number of sources of income <strong>and</strong> the balance among<br />

the different sources. Thus, a household with two sources of income would be more diversified than a<br />

household with just one source, <strong>and</strong> a household with two income sources, each contributing 50<br />

percent of the total, would be more diversified than a household with one source accounting for 90<br />

percent of the income (for example, see Joshi et al, 2002).<br />

A second definition of diversification concerns the switch from subsistence food production<br />

to the commercial agriculture. For example, Delgado <strong>and</strong> Siamwalla (1997: 13) argue that “’farm<br />

diversification’ as an objective in African smallholder agriculture should refer primarily to the part of<br />

farm household output undertaken specifically for cash generation.” This type of diversification<br />

could also be described as agricultural commercialization. It does not necessarily involve an increase<br />

in the number or balance of income sources. For example, a farmer may move from producing<br />

various grains, tubers, <strong>and</strong> vegetables for own consumption to specializing in one or a few cash crops.<br />

A third definition focuses on switching from low-value crop production to higher-value crops,<br />

livestock, <strong>and</strong> non-farm activities. Although “low-value crops” are sometimes defined in terms of the<br />

value per unit of weight, it is probably more useful to define them as crops that generate high<br />

economic returns per unit of labor or l<strong>and</strong>. This definition focuses on diversification as a source of<br />

income growth <strong>and</strong> a potential means for poverty reduction.<br />

Another way to classify definitions of diversification is by specifying the sectors that are<br />

becoming more important as sources of income. As mentioned in Chapter 1, income diversification is<br />

often used to describe expansion in the importance of non-farm income, including off-farm wage<br />

labor <strong>and</strong> self-employment in small enterprises (see Reardon, 1997; Escobal, 2001). <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

into non-farm activities at the household, regional, or national level is often associated with rising<br />

Page 9


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

income. At the national level, this is equivalent to structural transformation, defined as the long-term<br />

decline in the percentage contribution of agriculture sector to gross domestic product (GDP) <strong>and</strong><br />

employment in growing economies. For example, the contribution of agriculture to GDP in Vietnam<br />

has declined from 35.3 percent in 1991 to 24.1 percent in 1995 <strong>and</strong> 19.9 percent in 2000 (GSO, 1997;<br />

Ministry of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development, 2002).<br />

Alternatively, agricultural diversification can be defined as the shift from crop production to<br />

livestock, fisheries, <strong>and</strong> forestry activities. Similarly, crop diversification refers more narrowly on<br />

shifts in the composition of crops grown. In contrast to non-farm diversification, crop diversification<br />

(defined in terms of the number of crops) is often greatest among poor subsistence farmers in rainfed<br />

agriculture. The reasons for this pattern are discussed below.<br />

2.1.2 Determinants of diversification<br />

Given the well-known gains associated with specialization, why do rural households in<br />

developing countries adopt multiple income-generating activities At least six factors can be<br />

identified:<br />

• First, multiple income sources can be a strategy to reduce risk. If each source of income<br />

fluctuates from year to year due to weather or other factors <strong>and</strong> the variations in income<br />

are not positively correlated across sources, then a household with multiple income<br />

sources will experience less income variability than a specialized household. Risk<br />

management may help explain crop diversification because some crops (such as cassava)<br />

are more drought tolerant 1 than others. In addition, risk management helps explain<br />

diversification from crop production into non-farm activities such as wage labor <strong>and</strong> nonfarm<br />

enterprises. When diversification is motivated by risk management, the household<br />

generally has to sacrifice in terms of average income. Thus, we expect diversification to<br />

occur when income sources are highly variable <strong>and</strong> when households are particularly risk<br />

averse. This is consistent with empirical research that shows that poor rural households<br />

practicing rain-fed agriculture in low-potential areas are more likely to have diverse<br />

income sources than richer households in areas with greater agro-ecological potential.<br />

• The second motivation for diversification is that there may be positive externalities<br />

between different activities so that total income from combining two activities is greater<br />

than if the household specialized in either one. For example, livestock production<br />

provides animal traction <strong>and</strong> manure which increase the productivity of crop production.<br />

Alternatively, crop production <strong>and</strong> agricultural processing may be more efficient when<br />

carried out by the same household if it reduces transportation costs.<br />

• Third, multiple income sources may be useful as an adaptation to missing or poorlyfunctioning<br />

markets. For example, if a household has plot of l<strong>and</strong> that is too small to fully<br />

occupy family labor, one option would be to rent or purchase additional l<strong>and</strong>. But if l<strong>and</strong><br />

markets do not exist, then the household may be forced to use its “surplus” labor in nonfarm<br />

enterprises or wage labor even if the return is lower. Alternatively, if credit markets<br />

do not operate efficiently <strong>and</strong> a household has a cash constraint, it may use non-farm<br />

activities to earn cash to pay for agricultural inputs.<br />

1 On the other h<strong>and</strong>, Quiroz <strong>and</strong> Valdez (1995) argue that crop diversification is unlikely to reduce<br />

income risk because the yields of different crops are closely correlated since they are both affected by weather.<br />

Page 10


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

• Fourth, labor productivity in an activity may be highly seasonal, creating an incentive to<br />

undertake additional activities when productivity in the first is low. This helps explain<br />

non-farm activities during the off-season in areas with rain-fed agriculture <strong>and</strong> one crop<br />

cycle per year. It also explains seasonal participation in agricultural wage labor during<br />

the harvest season of a major cash crop.<br />

• Fifth, heterogeneity in the skills or employment opportunities of household members can<br />

motivate the household to diversify. Even if individual members are specialized in their<br />

income sources, the household may be diversified.<br />

• Finally, diverse income sources may be motivated by the combination of diverse<br />

consumption needs <strong>and</strong> high transaction costs in purchasing consumer goods. In<br />

economic terms, high transaction costs imply that production <strong>and</strong> consumption decisions<br />

are not separable, so that consumption needs affect production decisions. For example, if<br />

a household lives far from roads <strong>and</strong> markets, the cost of buying <strong>and</strong> selling goods will be<br />

high, forcing it to diversify in order to satisfy its own dem<strong>and</strong> for different types of food<br />

<strong>and</strong> non-food goods.<br />

If we define diversification as the process of switching from low-value crops to higher-value<br />

crops <strong>and</strong> non-crop activities, then an obvious question is why would a farmer choose to grow lowvalue<br />

crops The explanation is that various barriers to entry keep some households from diversifying<br />

into the high-value crops <strong>and</strong> activities. Indeed, these barriers to entry probably contribute to the<br />

higher returns from these activities. <strong>Diversification</strong> into high-value crops <strong>and</strong> activities may be<br />

inhibited by:<br />

• Lack of liquidity <strong>and</strong> lack of access to credit. This constraint is particularly applicable in<br />

the case of fruit <strong>and</strong> other tree crops that require several years to mature. It is also a<br />

barrier to entry into some non-farm enterprise sectors that require equipment, such as<br />

grain milling,<br />

• Lack of information about production methods <strong>and</strong> markets. This constraint is<br />

particularly relevant for new <strong>and</strong> specialty crops, aquaculture, fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables, <strong>and</strong><br />

other perishable commodities.<br />

• Lack of education or language skills necessary to acquire needed information. This issue<br />

affects ethnic minorities in many countries <strong>and</strong> may be an issue for female-headed<br />

households in some areas.<br />

• Poor infrastructure which reduces the farm-gate price of crops <strong>and</strong> raises the farm-gate<br />

cost of purchased inputs. This constraint is more binding for households in remote<br />

locations <strong>and</strong> for crops that are either perishable or have a low value-bulk ratio.<br />

• Insufficient l<strong>and</strong> or labor to diversify into non-food crops <strong>and</strong> other activities. Poor<br />

farmers are underst<strong>and</strong>ably reluctant to depend on the market for their food, so they often<br />

prefer to supplement food production with high-value crops <strong>and</strong> other activities rather<br />

than reallocate a large portion of l<strong>and</strong> to high-value crop production. This constraint<br />

affects areas where the population density is high relative to the agro-ecological potential<br />

of the l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

• Lack of social capital. Social capital refers to the network of friends <strong>and</strong> business<br />

associates with which a person has some level of mutual trust. In the agricultural sector,<br />

Page 11


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

social capital is particularly important for traders than assemble crops, those trading in<br />

perishable commodities, <strong>and</strong> those engaged in long-distance trade.<br />

These constraints hint at the types of public interventions that would be necessary to lift these<br />

barriers <strong>and</strong> facilitate the participation of poor rural households in these high-value activities. Of<br />

course, if such efforts are successful, they will exp<strong>and</strong> the supply <strong>and</strong> may depress the market price.<br />

Stories of development projects that flood the market with cabbage or apricots, pushing down the<br />

price to the point where it is not worth harvesting the crop, are common in many developing<br />

countries. But this situation is avoidable if careful market research can confirm that the commodity is<br />

tradable, that domestic dem<strong>and</strong> is elastic, or that the project area has some advantages over other<br />

production zones.<br />

2.1.3 Effects of diversification<br />

Several concerns have been raised about the process of income diversification <strong>and</strong><br />

commercialization in the rural areas of developing countries (see Pingali <strong>and</strong> Rosegrant, 1995, for a<br />

more in-depth discussion). First, a common critique is that switching from food production to cash<br />

crop production may adversely affect food security <strong>and</strong> nutrition. This view is disputed by Von Braun<br />

(1995), who summarizes a series of studies based on household surveys that compare income, food<br />

intake, <strong>and</strong> nutritional status of farm households. The conclusion is that farmers involved in cash crop<br />

production were generally better off on various dimensions than similar households that were more<br />

subsistence oriented. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, commercialization combined with inappropriate policies or<br />

institutional failures can result in adverse effects for poor households.<br />

Others have noted that diversification into high-value commodities may increase income<br />

inequality <strong>and</strong> create social differentiation. Henin (2002) expresses similar concerns in the case of<br />

Vietnam. A number of studies have shown that rural non-farm income is positively correlated with<br />

total household income, the implication being that non-farm activities exacerbate income inequalities<br />

in rural areas (Reardon, 1997; Lanjouw <strong>and</strong> Lanjouw, 2001).<br />

A third issue of concern is the environmental impact of commercial agricultural production.<br />

In some cases, rapid expansion of a commercial crop (often stimulated by high world prices) has led<br />

to deforestation <strong>and</strong> other unsustainable production practices. The use of chemical inputs may have<br />

adverse effects on farmer health <strong>and</strong> productivity <strong>and</strong>/or contaminate local groundwater.<br />

2.1.4 International patterns in diversification<br />

As the per capita income of countries increases, the contribution of the agricultural sector to<br />

gross domestic product tends to decline. This structural transformation is seen clearly by comparing<br />

the share of agriculture in low- <strong>and</strong> high-income countries (see Figure 2-1). Some of this shift is due<br />

to urbanization <strong>and</strong> some to the growing importance of non-farm income sources in rural areas,<br />

though the patterns vary across countries. Numerous studies of income <strong>and</strong> crop diversification have<br />

Page 12


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

been carried out, although they are sometimes difficult to compare due to differences in the definition<br />

of diversification. A selective review of some of these studies illustrates many of the points made in<br />

Sections 2.1.2 <strong>and</strong> 2.1.3 of this chapter.<br />

Figure 2-1. Structural transformation across countries<br />

80<br />

Share of agriculture in GDP (%)<br />

70<br />

60<br />

Laos<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

Vietnam<br />

20<br />

10<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong><br />

Japan<br />

0<br />

100 1,000 10,000 100,000<br />

Per capita income (US$)<br />

Source: World Bank, 2003.<br />

Joshi et al (2002) examine the trends in diversification in South Asia using area <strong>and</strong><br />

production statistics <strong>and</strong> the Simpson Index of Diversity (SID). The SID is a measure of the number<br />

of income sources <strong>and</strong> the balance among them (see Section 2.2.3 for more information). They show<br />

that the diversity of crop production has increased over the past two decades in most South Asian<br />

countries. In India, the southern <strong>and</strong> western regions are diversifying away from grains toward<br />

pulses, oil seeds, fruits, <strong>and</strong> vegetables. In the northern region, farmers are turning from coarse grains<br />

to commercial production of rice, wheat, <strong>and</strong> (to a lesser degree) non-grain crops. The eastern region<br />

is poorer <strong>and</strong> less developed. Agriculture is dominated by rice, but the non-rice areas are quite<br />

diverse. Carrying out state-level time-series econometric analysis, they show that diversification is<br />

associated with road density, urbanization, average farm size, <strong>and</strong> per capita income. Rainfall is also<br />

a significant factor: low-rainfall areas have more diverse cropping patterns than high-rainfall areas.<br />

They conclude that diversification from coarse grains to high-yielding rice <strong>and</strong> wheat has had positive<br />

effects on food security, while diversification toward cash crops has boosted employment per hectare<br />

<strong>and</strong> agricultural exports.<br />

Page 13


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

Reardon (1997) summarizes the results of 27 studies of rural non-farm employment in sub-<br />

Saharan Africa. He finds that non-farm activities are relatively important in rural areas, accounting<br />

for 30-50 percent of income in many cases. In general, non-farm wage labor is more important than<br />

non-farm self-employment. Non-farm rural income tends to be more important in areas near cities<br />

with good infrastructure <strong>and</strong> high population density. Finally, non-farm income is more important<br />

among better-off rural households.<br />

In a study of rural households in Ethiopia, Block <strong>and</strong> Webb (2001) find that diversification<br />

out of crop production is associated with higher-income households, a higher dependency ratio, maleheaded<br />

households, <strong>and</strong> location in the highl<strong>and</strong>s (a region endowed with good soils <strong>and</strong> higher<br />

rainfall). One of the motivations for diversifying out of crops, often into livestock activities, is to<br />

provide insurance against drought. According to a survey, farmers believe that households with large<br />

herds are less vulnerable to drought.<br />

Delgado <strong>and</strong> Siamwalla (1997) examine patterns of income diversification in Asia <strong>and</strong> Africa.<br />

They note that African farmers often have highly diversified crop mixes as a strategy to reduce risks<br />

associated with bad weather. In many Asian countries, crop diversification is associated with<br />

reducing the importance of rice <strong>and</strong> moving toward fruits, vegetables, <strong>and</strong> livestock activities. This<br />

type of diversification raises income but exposes farmers to market risks, particularly when the<br />

commodity is perishable. They argue that governments can play a constructive role in facilitating<br />

institutions, such as cooperatives <strong>and</strong> contract farming, that facilitate diversification into high-value<br />

commodities, thus raising rural income.<br />

Liquidity constraints are often an important factor in the ability of households to diversify<br />

into more remunerative activities. In Cote d’Ivoire, the 1994 currency devaluation increased the<br />

incentives to grow cocoa, cotton, <strong>and</strong> other export crops, but richer households were better able to<br />

take advantage of these opportunities, presumably due to greater liquidity. In Kenya, a food-for-work<br />

program increased the liquidity of poor farmers, allowing them to diversify into non-crop activities<br />

<strong>and</strong> avoid destocking livestock in drought years (Barrett et al, 2001).<br />

Another study compares diversification in Rw<strong>and</strong>a, Kenya, <strong>and</strong> Cote d’Ivoire. <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

away from crop production is greatest in areas with low rainfall <strong>and</strong> poor soils. Although unskilled<br />

labor income is associated with poor households, most other forms of non-farm income are positively<br />

correlated with income. The fact that income diversity is greater among higher-income households<br />

contradicts the idea that diversification is a risk management strategy (since we would expect the poor<br />

to be more risk averse). On the other h<strong>and</strong>, it suggests that non-farm activities involve some barriers<br />

to entry, such as education or capital, that make it difficult for poor households to participate (Barrett<br />

et al, 2000b).<br />

In Peru, non-farm activities make up roughly half of all rural income, though the percentage<br />

varies widely across regions <strong>and</strong> households. The share of income from non-farm enterprises is<br />

Page 14


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

positively correlated with education, electrification, proximity to market, <strong>and</strong> the value of crop output<br />

per hectare (Escobal, 2001).<br />

One study estimates the relationship between income diversification <strong>and</strong> household welfare in<br />

Zimbabwe. Using household surveys carried out in 1990-91 <strong>and</strong> 1995-96, the study measured income<br />

diversification by the number of income sources, the share of non-farm income, <strong>and</strong> the Simpson<br />

index of diversity. The author finds that in rural areas, richer households had more diversified income<br />

sources, while in urban areas the reverse was true (Ersado, 2003).<br />

A recent study of West Punjab (India) looked at long-term trends in agricultural production<br />

over the 20 th century (Kurosaki, 2003). This study found that area increase accounted for 71 percent<br />

of the growth in an index of agricultural output 2 over 1903-1952, but in the period 1952-1992 the<br />

most important contributors were yield increases (53 percent) <strong>and</strong> diversification (7 percent), where<br />

diversification was defined as the reallocation of l<strong>and</strong> toward higher-yielding crops. In the first<br />

period, rice yield growth was due to concentration of rice production in the districts with higher <strong>and</strong><br />

growing yields, while in the second period, it was due to higher yields in each district. Finally,<br />

analysis across districts indicates that road density is associated with diversification in the first period<br />

<strong>and</strong> with specialization in the second period (Kurosaki, 2003).<br />

Several studies have looked at the patterns of diversification in Vietnam. Pederson <strong>and</strong><br />

Annou (1999) examine the patterns of diversification using the 1992-93 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards<br />

Survey. They find that agricultural diversification (defined as the share of non-rice output in<br />

agricultural output) is associated with small farms, small irrigated areas, <strong>and</strong> higher levels of<br />

education. In addition, they find that households whose crop production is relatively specialized in<br />

rice tend to have more non-farm income diversification. This may suggest that household prefer some<br />

form of diversification, either in non-rice production or in non-farm activities.<br />

Henin (2002) provides a description of diversification patterns in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s,<br />

focusing on Lang Son province. He argues that doi moi policies have increased income <strong>and</strong><br />

stimulated income diversification. Farmers in the study area have adopted modern rice varieties <strong>and</strong><br />

fertilizer (though they continue to use local varieties as well) <strong>and</strong> have exp<strong>and</strong>ed production of cash<br />

crops such as sugarcane, peanuts, soybeans, tobacco, cinnamon, tea, <strong>and</strong> anis. Non-agricultural<br />

activities are limited by the lack of rural industries, but some households earn income from porter<br />

work, collecting firewood, bicycle <strong>and</strong> motorbike repair, <strong>and</strong> so on. Farmers identify a number of<br />

constraints to diversification <strong>and</strong> poverty reduction: lack of capital, shortage of paddy l<strong>and</strong>, poor<br />

access to markets, poor irrigation infrastructure, <strong>and</strong> low quality education. Borrowing from the<br />

formal sector, even from the concessionary Hunger Alleviation <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> Reduction Fund, is not<br />

popular due to the high interest rates, short maturity of the loans, <strong>and</strong> complex procedures. Many<br />

2<br />

Because price data were not available throughout the 89-year period of the study, the author<br />

constructed an index that combines production data on 12 major crops using fixed 1960 prices.<br />

Page 15


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

farmers borrow informally from members of their kin network. Although the reforms have increased<br />

income, they have also increased inequality, social differentiation, <strong>and</strong> a deterioration in some social<br />

services.<br />

A recent book contains a number of detailed studies of changes in l<strong>and</strong> use <strong>and</strong> income<br />

sources in Bac Kan Province (Castella <strong>and</strong> Dang Dinh Quang, 2002). Most of the studies provide a<br />

long-term perspectives, describing changes in l<strong>and</strong>-use patterns as a result of various changes in<br />

policy <strong>and</strong> technology: collectivization in the late 1950s, the introduction of high-yielding rice<br />

varieties in the late 1960s, the contract system under Decree 100 in 1981, decollectivization of l<strong>and</strong> in<br />

the years following Resolution 10 of 1988, <strong>and</strong> the L<strong>and</strong> Law of 1993, which began the process of<br />

allocating l<strong>and</strong>-use certificates. The studies use satellite imagery to document the progressive loss of<br />

forest cover, particularly during the 1980s.<br />

One study in Cho Moi District argues that the allocation of l<strong>and</strong> has been successful in<br />

stimulating intensification of lowl<strong>and</strong> rice production, diversification in the upl<strong>and</strong>s (particularly in<br />

fruit), <strong>and</strong> preservation of forestl<strong>and</strong>. Intensification of lowl<strong>and</strong> production is not an alternative to<br />

upl<strong>and</strong> diversification; in fact, intensification has produced the liquidity <strong>and</strong> food security needed to<br />

allow households to diversify on their upl<strong>and</strong> plots (Fatoux et al, 2002).<br />

A study of Ba Be District highlights the importance of accessibility in determining income<br />

opportunities. In remote villages, farmers rely on subsistence crop <strong>and</strong> livestock production. They<br />

have fewer opportunities to sell their output, speak with extension agents, benefit from government<br />

programs, or obtain non-farm employment. As a result, they tend to be poorer than villages on main<br />

roads close to urban centers, even if they have irrigated lowl<strong>and</strong>s (Alther et al, 2002).<br />

And a study in Cho Don District found that the ethnicity is becoming less useful as a predictor<br />

of livelihood strategies. Historically, the Tay were sedentary lowl<strong>and</strong> rice farmers, while the Dao<br />

were nomadic <strong>and</strong> practiced shifting cultivation in upl<strong>and</strong> areas. As a result of l<strong>and</strong> allocations, l<strong>and</strong><br />

purchases, <strong>and</strong> other factors, the distinction between Tay <strong>and</strong> Dao livelihood strategies is weak. Both<br />

Tay <strong>and</strong> Dao farmers who have access to lowl<strong>and</strong> paddy l<strong>and</strong> are sedentary <strong>and</strong> grow irrigated rice,<br />

while those without (both Tay <strong>and</strong> Dao) are forced to practice shifting cultivation (Castella et al,<br />

2002).<br />

Page 16


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

2.2 Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

For the purpose of this report, we define the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s to include the provinces in the<br />

Northeast <strong>and</strong> Northwest regions 3 . This region is characterized by:<br />

• Rugged upl<strong>and</strong> terrain. Much of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s consists of hills <strong>and</strong> low<br />

mountains between 500 <strong>and</strong> 1000 meters above sea level, but there are mountainous area<br />

above 1000 meters (Nguyen Trong Dieu, 1995).<br />

• Poor infrastructure. According to the 1994 Traffic Survey, the length of asphalted roads<br />

in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region was 3271 kilometers, giving it a road density of 0.032<br />

km/km 2 . By comparison, the national average is 0.045 km/km 2 (GSO, 1998: 779).<br />

• Low population density. The population density in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s is 111<br />

people/km 2 , which is low compared to the national figure of 231 people/km 2<br />

• A large ethnic minority population. According to the data from the 1998 VLSS, 47<br />

percent of the heads of household in the rural areas of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s belong to an<br />

ethnic minority. In contrast, the figure for Vietnam as a whole is just 12 percent.<br />

• Low levels of urbanization. According to GSO estimates for 2000, 16 percent of the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> population lives in urban areas, compared to 23 percent nationally<br />

(GSO, 2001).<br />

• Importance of the agricultural sector. Agriculture, forestry, <strong>and</strong> fishing account for about<br />

42 percent of the gross domestic product of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region. For Vietnam as<br />

a whole, this sector accounts for just 24 percent of GDP (GSO, 2001).<br />

• A high incidence of poverty. According to the 1999 Vietnam Household Living<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey carried out by the General Statistical Office, the incidence of income<br />

poverty in the Northeast <strong>and</strong> Northwest was 41 percent, higher than any other region,<br />

though only slightly greater than in the North Central Coast <strong>and</strong> the Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

(GSO, 2000: 74). Similarly, the 1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey estimated the<br />

incidence of poverty in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s to be 59 percent, the highest of any region.<br />

(Joint Working Group, 2000)<br />

Behind these generalizations, however, a considerable amount of diversity exists within the<br />

region. For example, across provinces, the population density varies from 36 to 395 people/km 2 , the<br />

per capita gross domestic product (GDP) varies from less than VND 1.4 million to 3.7 million, <strong>and</strong><br />

the share of agriculture in GDP ranges from less than 10 percent to over 60 percent. Another<br />

important point is that, although much of the region is poor, rural, <strong>and</strong> geographically isolated, this<br />

does not imply that the rural economy is stagnant or that the region is being “left behind.” In fact, the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s is undergoing the same transformations (economic growth, urbanization,<br />

3<br />

The number of provinces in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s increased from 13 in 1995 (when it was called the<br />

North Mountain <strong>and</strong> Midl<strong>and</strong>s) to 16 in 1999 (when it was divided into two regions: the Northeast <strong>and</strong><br />

Northwest). Since 1999, two provinces (Vinh Phuc <strong>and</strong> Bac Ninh) have been reclassified as part of the Red<br />

River Delta, leaving 14 provinces: eleven in the Northeast (Ha Giang, Cao Bang, Lao Cai, Bac Kan, Lang Son,<br />

Tuyen Quang, Yen Bai, Thai Nguyen, Phu Tho, Bac Giang, <strong>and</strong> Quang Ninh) <strong>and</strong> three in the Northwest (Lai<br />

Chau, Son La, <strong>and</strong> Hoa Binh).<br />

Page 17


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

commercialization, poverty reduction, etc.) that are occurring elsewhere in Vietnam <strong>and</strong> in many<br />

cases at the same rate. Thus, it is important to underst<strong>and</strong> both the diversity within the region <strong>and</strong> the<br />

trends over time. This chapter uses data from various sources to describe the geographic,<br />

demographic, <strong>and</strong> economic diversity of the region. When possible, we present statistics for 1995 <strong>and</strong><br />

2000 to demonstrate the changes occurring in the region.<br />

2.2.1 Geography<br />

The Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s covers about 102 thous<strong>and</strong> square kilometers, representing a little less<br />

than one third of the area of Vietnam. It is bordered by China on the north <strong>and</strong> the Lao P.D.R. to the<br />

west <strong>and</strong> south. The region is bisected diagonally by the Red River (Song Hong) which runs from the<br />

northwest to the southeast. Running parallel south of the Red River is the Black River (Song Da).<br />

Much of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s consists of hills <strong>and</strong> low mountains with elevations between<br />

500 <strong>and</strong> 1000 meters above sea level. The three provinces of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s to the west of the<br />

Red River have large areas over 1000 meters, particularly in the Hoang Lien Son, a range than runs<br />

between the Red River <strong>and</strong> the Black River. In fact, Fan Si Pan, the highest peak in Vietnam at 3143<br />

meters above sea level, is in the province of Lao Cai in this range. The Northeast, the elevations are<br />

not as high, but there are areas over 1000 meters. In Figure 2-2, the Red River valley can be seen as<br />

a thin line entering Vietnam from the northwest, passing through Lai Chau, Yen Bai, <strong>and</strong> Phu Tho.<br />

The rugged Hoan Lien Son mountain range is visible running parallel to the Red River to the south.<br />

Figure 2-2 maps an index of accessibility based on the time it takes to get to the district<br />

capital. The travel time is calculated using assumed fastest possible travel speed, taking into account<br />

l<strong>and</strong> cover, road quality, river navigability, the presence of bridges or ferries at the river-crossings,<br />

<strong>and</strong> slope. The red <strong>and</strong> purple zones represent areas with less access (greater travel time to the district<br />

headquarters). It is clear that Lai Chau is one of the least accessible provinces in the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s, followed by Son La <strong>and</strong> Lao Cai. Provinces in the Northeast generally have better<br />

accessibility.<br />

2.2.2 Population<br />

As shown in Table 2-1, the region is home to 11.2 million people 4 , giving it a population<br />

density of 111 people per square kilometer (km 2 ). As mentioned above, however, there is<br />

considerable variation. Four provinces have more than 1 million inhabitants: Bac Giang, Phu Tho,<br />

Thai Nguyen, <strong>and</strong> Quang Ninh. These four are also the most densely populated provinces in the<br />

region with 173-395 people/km 2 . Three of the four are located on the edges of the Red River Delta,<br />

with significant lowl<strong>and</strong> areas <strong>and</strong> relatively good proximity to Hanoi. Quang Ninh is a special case<br />

among these provinces because it is on the coast, allowing it to benefit from a large fishing sector, <strong>and</strong><br />

4<br />

The figures given here are GSO estimates for the year 2000. The estimates are slightly higher than<br />

the results of the 1999 Census which counted 11.1 million people in the 16 provinces considered here.<br />

Page 18


Figure 2-2. Elevation of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region<br />

Source: Elevation data from USGS GTOPO30, 2003.


Figure 2-3. Index of accessibility in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region<br />

Source: Spatial analysis of GIS data from the Center for Remote Sensing & Geomatics.


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

Table 2-1. General indicators for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s by province in 1995 <strong>and</strong> 2000<br />

Year<br />

Population<br />

Population<br />

growth rate<br />

Population<br />

density<br />

Agricultural<br />

population<br />

density<br />

(rural<br />

population/<br />

hectare of<br />

crop l<strong>and</strong>)<br />

Urban<br />

population<br />

GDP per<br />

capita<br />

(1000 1994<br />

VND/<br />

person)<br />

Growth rate<br />

in GDP per<br />

capita<br />

(1000<br />

persons) (percent)<br />

(population/<br />

km 2 )<br />

(percent)<br />

(percent)<br />

Ha Giang 1995 550.3 70 5.00 9% 945<br />

2000 618.4 2.4% 78 4.67 11% 1,374 8%<br />

Cao Bang 1995 489.2 73 4.99 10% 1,202<br />

2000 497.4 0.3% 74 5.27 13% 2,171 13%<br />

Lao Cai 1995 550.1 68 6.32 17% 1,366<br />

2000 613.6 2.2% 76 5.85 17% 1,556 3%<br />

Bac Kan 1995 254.2 52 8.16 13% 1,068<br />

2000 280.7 2.0% 58 6.43 15% 1,461 6%<br />

Lang Son 1995 679.2 82 7.22 17% 1,645<br />

2000 710.7 0.9% 86 5.32 19% 2,436 8%<br />

Tuyen Quang 1995 638.8 109 7.21 11% 1,379<br />

2000 685.5 1.4% 117 6.85 9% 1,957 7%<br />

Yen Bai 1995 647.7 94 7.24 19% 1,382<br />

2000 691.6 1.3% 100 6.22 20% 1,938 7%<br />

Thai Nguyen 1995 1,005.3 284 7.92 20% 1,662<br />

2000 1,054.1 1.0% 298 6.22 21% 1,984 4%<br />

Phu Tho 1995 1,211.7 344 8.96 10% 1,533<br />

2000 1,273.5 1.0% 362 7.87 14% 2,184 7%<br />

Bac Giang 1995 1431 374 6.67 6% 1,326<br />

2000 1,509.3 1.1% 395 6.66 7% 1,771 6%<br />

Quang Ninh 1995 941.7 160 7.50 43% 2,439<br />

2000 1,017.7 1.6% 173 6.89 44% 3,708 9%<br />

Lai Chau 1995 535.5 32 4.99 12% 1,440<br />

2000 613.3 2.8% 36 5.12 12% 1,614 2%<br />

Son La 1995 811.7 58 6.15 13% 884<br />

2000 906.8 2.2% 65 5.05 11% 1,369 9%<br />

Hoa Binh 1995 718.5 154 6.31 14% 1,255<br />

2000 767.6 1.3% 165 5.77 14% 2,033 10%<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 1995 10,464.6 104 6.73 15% 1,446<br />

2000 11,240.1 1.4% 111 6.06 16% 2,030 7%<br />

Annual growth 1.4% 1.4% -2.09 1.4% 7.0%<br />

Source: Calculations based on data from GSO (2001).<br />

because it has large coal mining operations. At the other extreme, Bac Kan has the smallest<br />

population (281 thous<strong>and</strong>) <strong>and</strong> Lai Chau, located in the far northwest bordering the Lao People’s<br />

Democratic Republic <strong>and</strong> the People’s Republic of China, has the lowest population density: 36<br />

people per square kilometer (see Table 2-1). The wide variation in population density is shown<br />

graphically in Figure 2-4. In much of the Red River Delta, the density is over 1000 people/km 2 .<br />

Outside the Delta, the population density falls off quickly to less than 200 people/km 2 .<br />

The agricultural population density, defined as the rural population per hectare of crop l<strong>and</strong>,<br />

varies much less. Most provinces have between 5.0 <strong>and</strong> 7.0 rural inhabitants per hectare of crop l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

In addition, while population density of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s increased, the agricultural population<br />

density has fallen due to the expansion of l<strong>and</strong> under cultivation. Over 1995-2000, the population<br />

growth rate for the region as a whole is estimated at 1.4 percent per year, though it differs widely<br />

Page 21


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

across provinces. In general, the least densely populated provinces experience the highest growth<br />

rates <strong>and</strong> vice versa. Lai Chau, the most sparsely populated province, has the highest rate of<br />

population growth: 2.8 percent per year. Son La, Lao Cai, <strong>and</strong> Ha Giang, also with low densities, also<br />

have growth rates of more than 2 percent. In contrast, the more densely populated provinces bordering<br />

the Red River delta have growth rates in the range of 1-1.5 percent (see Table 2-1).<br />

Overall, 16 percent of the people in the region lived in urban areas in 2000, up slightly from<br />

15 percent in 1995. The degree of urbanization tends to range between 10 <strong>and</strong> 20 percent across<br />

provinces. Quang Ninh is again an exception with the urban areas accounting for 44 percent of the<br />

population. Bac Giang <strong>and</strong> Tuyen Quang have urbanization rates somewhat below 10 percent (see<br />

Table 2-1).<br />

Figure 2-5 shows the main ethnic group in each commune in northern Vietnam. Note that the<br />

map indicates the most common ethnic group, but this group does not necessarily constitute a<br />

majority of the population in that commune. The map shows that the Kinh (ethnic Vietnamese) are the<br />

main group in the Delta region, as well as in most of Bac Giang, the southern half of Thai Nguyen, the<br />

northern part of Phu Tho, <strong>and</strong> parts of Yen Bai. The Tay, the most numerous of the ethnic minorities,<br />

live among the Nung in the valleys <strong>and</strong> plains of Bac Kan, northern Tuyen Quang, <strong>and</strong> parts of other<br />

provinces in the Northeast. The Tay are more similar culturally <strong>and</strong> economically to the Kinh than<br />

many minority groups. The Nung, the second most numerous minority, are concentrated in Lang Son<br />

<strong>and</strong> Cao Bang. The Thai are the main ethnic group in much of Son La province <strong>and</strong> parts of Lai Chau.<br />

The Muong are found in Hoa Binh <strong>and</strong> parts of Phu Tho <strong>and</strong> Son La. The Hmong (Meo) are more<br />

spread out, being found in Son La, Lai Chau, Yen Bai, <strong>and</strong> northern Ha Giang, often living at higher<br />

altitudes (above 1500 meters). The Dao live at middle altitudes (700-1000 m) are similarly scattered<br />

(Nguyen Trong Dieu, 1995).<br />

2.2.3 L<strong>and</strong> use <strong>and</strong> agriculture<br />

Contribution of agriculture to GDP<br />

One measure of the importance of the agricultural sector is its contribution to gross domestic<br />

product (GDP). Agriculture (defined broadly to include crops. livestock, fishing, <strong>and</strong> forestry)<br />

accounts for 24 percent of national GDP, but 42 percent of the GDP in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. As<br />

shown in Table 2-2, agriculture plays a particularly important role in the poorer, more remote border<br />

provinces such as Ha Giang, Cao Bang, <strong>and</strong> Son La, where it represents over half of GDP.<br />

Agriculture plays a somewhat smaller role in the higher-income interior provinces close to Hanoi such<br />

as Thai Nguyen <strong>and</strong> Phu Tho, where it is 30-40 percent of the total. Quang Ninh is the most industrial<br />

<strong>and</strong> the highest-income province in the region. Agriculture in Quang Ninh province accounts for just<br />

9 percent of GDP, while industry <strong>and</strong> construction (including mining) represents almost half of GDP.<br />

Page 22


Figure 2-4. Population density in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region<br />

Source: Analysis of data from the 1999 Population <strong>and</strong> Housing Census.


Figure 2-5. Main ethnic group in each commune of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1999 Population <strong>and</strong> Housing Census.


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

Table 2-2. Structure of gross domestic product in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

by province in 1995 <strong>and</strong> 2000<br />

Agric<br />

ulture, forestry,<br />

Year & fishing<br />

Industry &<br />

construction Services Total<br />

Ha Giang 1995 69% 15% 16% 100%<br />

2000 54% 21% 25% 100%<br />

Cao Bang 1995 73% 7% 19% 100%<br />

2000 56% 16% 29% 100%<br />

Lao Cai 1995 51% 22% 27% 100%<br />

2000 48% 22% 30% 100%<br />

Bac Kan 1995 71% 6% 23% 100%<br />

2000 66% 9% 25% 100%<br />

Lang Son 1995 62% 8% 30% 100%<br />

2000 50% 11% 38% 100%<br />

Tuyen Quang 1995 56% 16% 28% 100%<br />

2000 52% 20% 29% 100%<br />

Yen Bai 1995 52% 26% 22% 100%<br />

2000 45% 28% 27% 100%<br />

Thai Nguyen 1995 38% 33% 28% 100%<br />

2000 39% 32% 29% 100%<br />

Phu Tho 1995 36% 31% 33% 100%<br />

2000 31% 37% 32% 100%<br />

Bac Giang 1995 53% 17% 29% 100%<br />

2000 55% 14% 31% 100%<br />

Quang Ninh 1995 11% 38% 50% 100%<br />

2000 9% 48% 43% 100%<br />

Lai Chau 1995 49% 14% 37% 100%<br />

2000 46% 18% 37% 100%<br />

Son La 1995 73% 10% 17% 100%<br />

2000 62% 10% 27% 100%<br />

Hoa Binh 1995 60% 6% 33% 100%<br />

2000 52% 17% 31% 100%<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 1995 47% 22% 31% 100%<br />

2000 42% 26% 33% 100%<br />

Change -5 +4 +2<br />

Source: Calculations based on data from GSO (2001).<br />

L<strong>and</strong> use<br />

The figures presented in Table 2-3 indicate that only a 15 percent of the l<strong>and</strong> area in the<br />

region is under cultivation. Almost half (47 percent) of the total l<strong>and</strong> area is classified as “unused<br />

l<strong>and</strong>”, which includes large tracts of l<strong>and</strong> that is unusable either because the topography is too rugged,<br />

because it is too remote, or because it has been degraded (the so-called “barren l<strong>and</strong>”). Another 37<br />

percent of the area is classified as forest l<strong>and</strong>, although this category includes actual forests <strong>and</strong> areas<br />

that are designated to be reclaimed as forest. The share of total l<strong>and</strong> being used for cultivation is<br />

lowest in Lai Chau (6 percent) <strong>and</strong> ranges from 11 to 15 percent in the other border provinces. The<br />

interior province of Bac Giang is the only province in the region with more than 50 percent of the<br />

total area devoted to crop production. Thai Nguyen <strong>and</strong> Phu Tho, two other provinces with lowl<strong>and</strong><br />

areas, good access, <strong>and</strong> a high population density, have more than 35 percent of the l<strong>and</strong> area in crops<br />

(see Table 2-3).<br />

Page 25


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

Table 2-3. L<strong>and</strong> resources <strong>and</strong> productivity in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s by province<br />

in 1995 <strong>and</strong> 2000<br />

Total l<strong>and</strong> area Total cropped Cropped area as<br />

Agricultural GDP<br />

per hectare<br />

Year<br />

area percent of total<br />

(1000 ha) (1000 ha) (percent)<br />

(million 1994 VND<br />

/cropped ha)<br />

Ha Giang 1995 788 100.2 13% 3.60<br />

2000 788 117.9 15% 3.87<br />

Cao Bang 1995 669 88.2 13% 4.89<br />

2000 669 82.1 12% 7.32<br />

Lao Cai 1995 806 72.3 9% 5.28<br />

2000 806 87.1 11% 5.31<br />

Bac Kan 1995 486 27.1 6% 7.14<br />

2000 486 37.1 8% 7.29<br />

Lang Son 1995 830 78.1 9% 8.90<br />

2000 830 108.3 13% 8.05<br />

Tuyen Quang 1995 587 78.8 13% 6.25<br />

2000 587 91.1 16% 7.60<br />

Yen Bai 1995 688 72.5 11% 6.39<br />

2000 688 88.9 13% 6.76<br />

Thai Nguyen 1995 354 101.5 29% 6.33<br />

2000 354 133.8 38% 6.03<br />

Phu Tho 1995 352 121.7 35% 5.47<br />

2000 352 139.2 40% 6.15<br />

Bac Giang 1995 382 201.6 53% 5.04<br />

2000 382 210.9 55% 6.99<br />

Quang Ninh 1995 590 71.6 12% 3.67<br />

2000 590 82.7 14% 4.27<br />

Lai Chau 1995 1692 94.5 6% 3.97<br />

2000 1692 105.4 6% 4.29<br />

Son La 1995 1405 114.9 8% 4.56<br />

2000 1405 159.7 11% 4.86<br />

Hoa Binh 1995 466 98 21% 5.55<br />

2000 466 114.4 25% 7.07<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 1995 10096 1321.0 13% 5.33<br />

2000 10096 1558.6 15% 6.08<br />

Annual growth 0.0% 3.4% 2.7%<br />

Source: Calculations based on data from GSO (2001).<br />

The last column in Table 2-3 shows the value of agricultural output per hectare of crop l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

This is one measure of crop diversification because as household diversify from low-value staple<br />

crops to higher-value commercial crops, this is reflected in rising value per hectare. On average,<br />

cropl<strong>and</strong> in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s produces VND 6.1 million per hectare (in constant 1994 prices).<br />

The provincial figures reveal two patterns. First, the value per hectare is generally greater in the<br />

interior provinces close to Hanoi than in the remote border provinces. For example. Ha Giang, Lai<br />

Chau, <strong>and</strong> Son La have values of less than VND 5 million per hectare of cropl<strong>and</strong>. And the interior<br />

provinces of Tuyen Quang, Yen Bai, Phu Tho, Bac Giang, Hoa Binh, <strong>and</strong> Thai Nguyen have<br />

agricultural output worth more than VND 6 million per hectare. There are some exceptions to this<br />

pattern, notably the high values found in Lang Son <strong>and</strong> Cao Bang. In the case of Lang Son, part of<br />

the explanation lies in the large forestry sector, which is included in the broad definition of<br />

Page 26


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

agriculture. In addition, Lang Son is the main gateway for exports to China, giving the province an<br />

advantage in producing for export.<br />

The second pattern that is evident is that the value of agricultural output per hectare increased<br />

substantially, rising from VND 5.3 million/ha in 1995 to VND 6.1 million/ha in 2000. This represents<br />

an increase of 2.2 percent per year. Although this increase is consistent with crop diversification, in<br />

which farmers shift from low-value to high-value crops, it may also reflect higher yields <strong>and</strong>/or higher<br />

crop prices. Thus, it is useful to examine the allocation of cropl<strong>and</strong> among different crops.<br />

Agricultural data from the General Statistics Office suggest that rice remains the dominant<br />

crop in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, but that the share of cropl<strong>and</strong> allocated to rice is declining. As shown<br />

in Table 2-4, sown rice area 5 has fallen from 50 percent of the total to 44 percent. Furthermore, this<br />

decline can be observed in every province except one (Bac Giang). In Bac Kan <strong>and</strong> Son La, the<br />

percentage of cropl<strong>and</strong> planted with rice declined dramatically, falling by more than 10 percentage<br />

points over the five-year period. Other food crops (maize, cassava, <strong>and</strong> sweet potatoes) show no net<br />

change for the region as a whole, but this masks some variation across provinces. Most provinces<br />

experienced a small decrease in the share of area allocated to non-rice food crops, but this was offset<br />

by large increases in Son La <strong>and</strong> Bac Kan. In Son La, maize production has grown strongly in recent<br />

years to supply the feed industry which in turn has been stimulated by the growth of urban dem<strong>and</strong> for<br />

poultry <strong>and</strong> pork.<br />

The share of cropl<strong>and</strong> allocated to vegetables <strong>and</strong> beans increased slightly, as did the share of<br />

area devoted to tea <strong>and</strong> coffee (of which tea represents 93 percent), while the share allocated to annual<br />

industrial crops fell slightly. But the most noteworthy trend is the growth in the share of cropl<strong>and</strong><br />

devoted to “other crops,” which has increased from 6 percent in 1995 to 11 percent in 2000. The<br />

largest increase is in the province of Lang Son, on the northern border with China. The category<br />

“other crops” presumably includes fruit trees, other tree crops, <strong>and</strong> agro-forestry plantations. The<br />

growth in litchi <strong>and</strong> longan production for domestic consumption <strong>and</strong> for export to China probably<br />

accounts for the main part of this increase. It should be noted, however, that we have calculated<br />

“other crops” as a residual of total crop area after subtracting the other crop categories.<br />

Crop production<br />

The falling share of cropl<strong>and</strong> allocated to rice cultivation raises questions about the impact of<br />

crop diversification on food security. Are farmers in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s sacrificing food security<br />

in pursuit of higher profits from vegetables, tea, <strong>and</strong> fruit The question is particularly relevant in<br />

light of the fact that the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s is the poorest region of Vietnam so food security is<br />

clearly an important issue. Table 2-5 shows that the amount of rice l<strong>and</strong> in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s has<br />

5 “Sown area” adds the areas planted in different seasons, so that one hectare of double-cropped rice is<br />

counted as two hectares.<br />

Page 27


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

remained virtually unchanged over the period 1995-2000. Furthermore, a crude measure 6 of rice<br />

cropping intensity suggests that it has increased only slightly, rising from 1.47 to 1.51 over the fiveyear<br />

period.<br />

Table 2-4. Allocation of cropped area in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s by province in 1995 <strong>and</strong> 2000<br />

Year<br />

Rice<br />

Other food<br />

crops<br />

Percentage of cropped area<br />

Annual<br />

industrial<br />

crops<br />

Vegetables<br />

& beans<br />

Coffee<br />

& tea<br />

Other<br />

crops<br />

---------------------------------------------(percent)--------------------------------------------<br />

Ha Giang 1995 29% 44% 8% 6% 7% 6% 100%<br />

2000 26% 39% 9% 8% 8% 9% 100%<br />

Cao Bang 1995 38% 43% 3% 12% 0% 4% 100%<br />

2000 35% 43% 5% 14% 0% 4% 100%<br />

Lao Cai 1995 46% 35% 8% 8% 2% 1% 100%<br />

2000 42% 34% 4% 9% 2% 9% 100%<br />

Bac Kan 1995 66% 19% 4% 7% 1% 3% 100%<br />

2000 50% 34% 4% 6% 1% 6% 100%<br />

Lang Son 1995 58% 21% 6% 9% 1% 5% 100%<br />

2000 43% 18% 5% 6% 1% 27% 100%<br />

Tuyen Quang 1995 51% 23% 4% 13% 5% 3% 100%<br />

2000 49% 22% 5% 14% 4% 7% 100%<br />

Yen Bai 1995 53% 21% 6% 4% 10% 7% 100%<br />

2000 45% 24% 6% 4% 12% 10% 100%<br />

Thai Nguyen 1995 58% 18% 7% 9% 8% 0% 100%<br />

2000 51% 20% 6% 8% 9% 6% 100%<br />

Phu Tho 1995 58% 19% 7% 6% 6% 4% 100%<br />

2000 51% 21% 7% 7% 6% 8% 100%<br />

Bac Giang 1995 54% 18% 6% 8% 0% 13% 100%<br />

2000 55% 14% 8% 6% 0% 17% 100%<br />

Quang Ninh 1995 63% 18% 9% 8% 0% 3% 100%<br />

2000 59% 16% 9% 5% 0% 11% 100%<br />

Lai Chau 1995 50% 38% 2% 6% 1% 3% 100%<br />

2000 49% 38% 3% 6% 2% 2% 100%<br />

Son La 1995 38% 34% 2% 12% 3% 11% 100%<br />

2000 26% 43% 3% 10% 4% 14% 100%<br />

Hoa Binh 1995 44% 28% 3% 13% 3% 9% 100%<br />

2000 38% 32% 5% 11% 2% 12% 100%<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 1995 50% 27% 5% 9% 3% 6% 100%<br />

2000 44% 27% 6% 8% 4% 11% 100%<br />

Change -6 0 +1 -1 +1 +5<br />

Source: Calculations based on data from GSO (2001).<br />

Total<br />

Combining the changes in rice l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> cropping intensity, the sown area of rice increased less than 1<br />

percent per year over the period 1995-2000. Paddy yields, however, have increased from 2.7 tons/ha<br />

in 1995 to 3.6 tons/ha in 2000, equivalent to an annual growth rate of almost 6 percent. The<br />

combined effect of the small increase in sown area <strong>and</strong> the large increase in yield is that rice produc-<br />

6<br />

Rice cropping intensity is calculated as the sum of sown rice area divided by the area planted with<br />

rice in any season. In the absence of data on the latter, we approximate rice intensity as the sum of spring <strong>and</strong><br />

winter area divided by larger of the two figures. This represents an upper limit on the true rice cropping<br />

intensity.<br />

Page 28


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

Table 2-5. Cereal production in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s by province in 1995 <strong>and</strong> 2000<br />

Rice Rice area<br />

Rice<br />

cropping<br />

Paddy Rice output Maize<br />

Maize<br />

output per<br />

Year l<strong>and</strong> sown intensity Paddy yield output per capita output capita<br />

(kg/ (1000 (kg/<br />

(1000 ha) (1000 ha) (ratio) (tons/ha)(1000 tons) person) tons person)<br />

Ha Giang 1995 23.5 29.3 1.25 2.80 81.9 98 45.4 83<br />

2000 23.7 31.2 1.32 3.88 121.0 129 71.3 115<br />

Cao Bang 1995 30.1 33.4 1.11 2.77 92.4 125 55.3 113<br />

2000 25.2 28.6 1.13 3.10 88.8 118 75.8 152<br />

Lao Cai 1995 26.4 33.1 1.25 2.49 82.5 99 27.7 50<br />

2000 27.7 36.4 1.31 3.07 111.7 120 38.3 62<br />

Bac Kan 1995 14.4 18.0 1.25 2.81 50.5 131 5.1 20<br />

2000 13.3 18.6 1.40 3.67 68.3 161 20.3 72<br />

Lang Son 1995 34.6 45.4 1.31 2.83 128.5 125 21.6 32<br />

2000 33.9 46.9 1.38 3.09 145.0 135 42.8 60<br />

Tuyen Quang 1995 26.4 40.3 1.53 3.32 133.7 138 24.8 39<br />

2000 26.6 44.5 1.67 4.47 198.9 192 36.6 53<br />

Yen Bai 1995 24.3 38.5 1.58 3.14 120.7 123 9.4 15<br />

2000 24.8 39.9 1.61 3.77 150.5 144 19.5 28<br />

Thai Nguyen 1995 37.6 59.2 1.57 3.03 179.4 118 10.1 10<br />

2000 42.7 68.6 1.61 3.89 267.1 167 30.6 29<br />

Phu Tho 1995 35.9 70.2 1.96 2.62 183.6 100 23.9 20<br />

2000 36.3 71.6 1.97 4.04 289.1 150 42.2 33<br />

Bac Giang 1995 60.4 109.8 1.82 2.62 287.7 133 13.9 10<br />

2000 64.3 115.0 1.79 4.14 475.6 208 28.9 19<br />

Quang Ninh 1995 28.0 45.1 1.61 2.59 116.7 82 6.0 6<br />

2000 30.1 48.4 1.61 3.64 176.0 114 12.9 13<br />

Lai Chau 1995 41.9 47.4 1.13 2.13 100.8 124 30.1 56<br />

2000 45.2 51.9 1.15 2.52 130.7 141 41.0 67<br />

Son La 1995 37.7 43.6 1.16 2.28 99.4 81 45.6 56<br />

2000 34.8 41.5 1.19 2.49 103.3 75 122.1 135<br />

Hoa Binh 1995 27.1 43.5 1.61 2.96 128.7 118 20.6 29<br />

2000 26.9 43.4 1.61 3.73 161.9 139 48.7 63<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 1995 446.7 656.8 1.47 2.72 1,786.5 113 339.5 32<br />

2000 454.5 686.5 1.51 3.62 2,487.9 146 631.0 56<br />

Annual growth 0.3% 0.9% 0.5% 5.9% 6.8% 5.3% 13.2% 11.6%<br />

Source: Calculations based on data from GSO (2001).<br />

tion in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s has grown 6.8 percent per year. Per capita rice production has grown<br />

from 113 kg/person to 146 kg/person, a growth rate of more than 5 percent annually. Thus, farmers<br />

are not sacrificing rice production to diversify into higher-value crops. Instead, they are moving<br />

slowly toward rice self-sufficiency on the basis of higher yields, while allocating any new l<strong>and</strong> to<br />

higher-value crops such as vegetables, fruit, <strong>and</strong> tea.<br />

Maize output has grown even more rapidly, rising 13 percent annually. Son La maize<br />

production has increased more than 160 percent over the five-year period, making it the main maize<br />

producer in the region. As mentioned earlier, the growing dem<strong>and</strong> for animal feed by poultry <strong>and</strong> pig<br />

producers s driving the dem<strong>and</strong> for maize.<br />

Page 29


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

2.2.4 <strong>Income</strong> <strong>and</strong> poverty<br />

The per capita gross domestic product of the region is VND 2.0 million (expressed in 1994<br />

prices). The per capita GDP ranges from below VND 1.4 million in Ha Giang <strong>and</strong> Son La to VND<br />

3.7 million in Quang Ninh. After Quang Ninh, no other province has a per capita GDP over VND<br />

2.5 million. Between 1995 <strong>and</strong> 2000, per capita GDP in the region has grown 7 percent per year. The<br />

slowest growing provinces over this period were Lao Cai <strong>and</strong> Lai Chau, whose economies grew at 2-3<br />

percent per year in per capita terms. Since these are some of the most remote regions, one might<br />

assume that there is a relationship between proximity to Hanoi <strong>and</strong> the growth rate. In fact, the<br />

relationship is not very clear. The fastest growing province in the region is Cao Bang, on the northern<br />

border with China <strong>and</strong> other border-provinces such as Ha Giang <strong>and</strong> Son La registered growth rates<br />

above the regional average (see Table 2.6).<br />

The incidences of poverty at the district level was estimated by combining data from the 1998 VLSS<br />

<strong>and</strong> the 1999 Population <strong>and</strong> Housing Census. The VLSS data were used to estimate econometrically<br />

the relationship between per capita expenditure <strong>and</strong> various household characteristics including size<br />

<strong>and</strong> composition of the household, housing characteristics, ownership of consumer durables, type of<br />

water source, type of toilet, <strong>and</strong> region. This relationship is then applied to the same household<br />

characteristics taken from the 1999 Census (see by Minot <strong>and</strong> Baulch, 2002 for more details). The<br />

results indicate that poverty is more widespread in the more remote districts, particularly those along<br />

the Lao <strong>and</strong> Chinese border. Closer to Hanoi <strong>and</strong> to the Red River Delta, the incidence of poverty is<br />

lower (see Figure 2-6). Using this method, the estimated national poverty rate from the Census data<br />

was 36.5 percent, compared to 37.4 percent as estimated directly from the 1998 VLSS. By contrast,<br />

the poverty rate in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s was 60 percent (see Table 2-6). The highest incidences<br />

of rural poverty were found in Lai Chau, Son La, Ha Giang, Lao Cai, <strong>and</strong> Cao Bang. These five<br />

provinces are not just the poorest in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, but according to this analysis, they are the<br />

poorest five provinces in the country. 7 The least poor rural areas in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s are those of<br />

Phu Tho, Bac Giang, <strong>and</strong> Thai Nguyen. These correspond to the provinces closes to Hanoi <strong>and</strong><br />

adjacent to the Red River Delta.<br />

7 The 95 percent confidence interval of these estimates is ± 6-8 percent, so we cannot say with<br />

confidence that, for example, the rural areas of Lai Chau are poorer than those of Son La.<br />

Page 30


Figure 2-6. Estimates of the incidence of poverty at the district level<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1999 Population <strong>and</strong> Housing Census <strong>and</strong> the 1998 VLSS.


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

Table 2-6. GDP per capita <strong>and</strong> estimated poverty<br />

GDP per capita<br />

Annual growth<br />

rate in GDP per<br />

capita<br />

Estimated<br />

incidence of<br />

poverty<br />

1995 2000 1995-2000 1999<br />

(1000 1994 VND/person) (percent) (percent)<br />

Ha Giang 945 1,374 8% 77%<br />

Cao Bang 1,202 2,171 13% 74%<br />

Lao Cai 1,366 1,556 3% 75%<br />

Bac Kan 1,068 1,461 6% 68%<br />

Lang Son 1,645 2,436 8% 72%<br />

Tuyen Quang 1,379 1,957 7% 63%<br />

Yen Bai 1,382 1,938 7% 64%<br />

Thai Nguyen 1,662 1,984 4% 49%<br />

Phu Tho 1,533 2,184 7% 48%<br />

Bac Giang 1,326 1,771 6% 49%<br />

Quang Ninh 2,439 3,708 9% 52%<br />

Lai Chau 1,440 1,614 2% 86%<br />

Son La 884 1,369 9% 79%<br />

Hoa Binh 1,255 2,033 10% 65%<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 1,446 2,030 7.0% 60%<br />

Source: GDP figures from GSO (2001).<br />

<strong>Poverty</strong> estimates from Minot <strong>and</strong> Baulch (2002).<br />

2.2.5 <strong>Income</strong> diversification<br />

Three measures of income diversification can be calculated from the GSO data. The first<br />

measure of diversification is the share of GDP generated outside the agricultural sector (defined<br />

broadly to include crops, livestock, fishing, <strong>and</strong> forestry). Overall, the non-agricultural share of GDP<br />

has increased from 53 to 58 percent. The increase is largest for Cao Bang (17 percentage point<br />

increase), Ha Giang (15 percentage points), Lang Son (12 percentage points) <strong>and</strong> Son La (11<br />

percentage points). The increase is quite small in Quang Ninh (from 89 to 91 percent), partly<br />

because the non-agricultural sector is already so dominant. And in Bac Giang <strong>and</strong> Thai Nguyen, the<br />

share of non-agricultural sector actually declined slightly. These are the only provinces that experienced<br />

this type of change (see Table 2-7 <strong>and</strong> Figure 2-7). Figure 2-8 plots the changes in the contribution of<br />

agriculture to GDP against changes in GDP per capita. Provinces with higher income tend to have a<br />

smaller agricultural component, but almost all provinces show both economic growth <strong>and</strong> declining<br />

share of agriculture. This process is known as the structural transformation of the economy.<br />

The second measure is the share of cultivated l<strong>and</strong> in crops other than rice. Overall, the share<br />

of non-rice crops has increased from 50 percent in 1995 to 56 percent in 2000. As mentioned earlier,<br />

the share of non-rice crops exp<strong>and</strong>ed in every province except one (Bac Giang), with the largest shifts<br />

occurring in Bac Kan, Lang Son <strong>and</strong> Son La (see Table 2-7).<br />

Page 32


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

The third measure of crop diversification is the share of cropl<strong>and</strong> allocated to non-food<br />

crops 8 . Under this definition, unlike the previous one, a shift from rice to maize would not be<br />

considered crop diversification. Overall, the share of cropl<strong>and</strong> planted with non-food crops grew<br />

from 23 percent to 28 percent. The largest increase was found in Lang Son, where it increased from<br />

21 percent to 39 percent, presumably in response to trade with China (see Table 2-7 <strong>and</strong> Figure 2-9).<br />

Table 2-7. Measure of income diversification in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

by province in 1995 <strong>and</strong> 2000<br />

Non-agricultural Non-rice area as Non-food area as<br />

Year<br />

GDP as<br />

percentage of total<br />

percentage of<br />

crop area<br />

percentage of<br />

crop area<br />

Ha Giang 1995 31% 71% 27%<br />

2000 46% 74% 34%<br />

Cao Bang 1995 27% 62% 19%<br />

2000 44% 65% 22%<br />

Lao Cai 1995 49% 54% 20%<br />

2000 52% 58% 24%<br />

Bac Kan 1995 29% 34% 15%<br />

2000 34% 50% 16%<br />

Lang Son 1995 38% 42% 21%<br />

2000 50% 57% 39%<br />

Tuyen Quang 1995 44% 49% 25%<br />

2000 48% 51% 29%<br />

Yen Bai 1995 48% 47% 26%<br />

2000 55% 55% 31%<br />

Thai Nguyen 1995 62% 42% 24%<br />

2000 61% 49% 29%<br />

Phu Tho 1995 64% 42% 23%<br />

2000 69% 49% 27%<br />

Bac Giang 1995 47% 46% 27%<br />

2000 45% 45% 32%<br />

Quang Ninh 1995 89% 37% 19%<br />

2000 91% 41% 26%<br />

Lai Chau 1995 51% 50% 12%<br />

2000 54% 51% 12%<br />

Son La 1995 27% 62% 28%<br />

2000 38% 74% 31%<br />

Hoa Binh 1995 40% 56% 27%<br />

2000 48% 62% 30%<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 1995 53% 50% 23%<br />

2000 58% 56% 28%<br />

Change +5 +6 +5<br />

Source: Calculations based on data from GSO (2001).<br />

8 Food crops are defined as rice, maize, sweet potatoes, <strong>and</strong> cassava<br />

Page 33


Figure 2-7. <strong>Diversification</strong> into non-agricultural activities over 1995-2000<br />

Source: Calculations based on data from GSO (2001).


Figure 2-8. Structural transformation of the provinces of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

80%<br />

1995<br />

70%<br />

Agriculture as % of GDP<br />

60%<br />

50%<br />

40%<br />

30%<br />

20%<br />

10%<br />

Ha Giang<br />

Cao Bang<br />

Lao Cai<br />

Bac Kan<br />

Lang Son<br />

Tuyen Quang<br />

Yen Bai<br />

Thai Nguyen<br />

Phu Tho<br />

Bac Giang<br />

Lai Chau<br />

Son La<br />

Hoa Binh<br />

2000<br />

0%<br />

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000<br />

GDP per capita (1000 VND)<br />

Source: Calculations based on data from GSO (2001)


Figure 2-9. <strong>Diversification</strong> into non-food crops over 1995-2000<br />

Source: Calculations based on data from GSO (2001).


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

2.3 Summary<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> has been defined in various ways. Some studies define it as an increase in the<br />

number of income-generating activities or the balance among them. Others focus on the transition<br />

from subsistence agriculture to commercial production. And a third definition emphasizes the<br />

reallocation of resources from crops with low returns (typically staple food crops) to crops <strong>and</strong><br />

activities with higher returns.<br />

Rural households adopt multiple income sources to manage risk, take advantage of<br />

externalities, adapt to missing markets, respond to heterogeneous skills in the household, or meet<br />

diverse consumption needs. <strong>Diversification</strong> into high-value activities is often inhibited by barriers to<br />

entry. These include lack of liquidity for investment, lack of information about production <strong>and</strong><br />

marketing, lack of education or language skills, lack of social capital, <strong>and</strong> poor infrastructure.<br />

Although income <strong>and</strong> crop diversification is usually considered a positive trend, some<br />

concerns have been raised about its impact on food security <strong>and</strong> nutrition, regarding the consequences<br />

for income inequality <strong>and</strong> social differentiation, <strong>and</strong> about its environmental sustainability. Empirical<br />

research on diversification show different patterns by region. There is evidence that crop<br />

diversification is greater among poor households in less favored agro-ecological zones, while nonfarm<br />

income diversification is associated with higher income, more education, <strong>and</strong> proximity to large<br />

markets.<br />

Turning our attention to the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, the topography is hilly to mountainous, with<br />

altitudes typically between 500 <strong>and</strong> 1000 meters but with some mountainous areas with peaks above<br />

3000 meters. The infrastructure is poor, leading to communities being relatively isolated from the rest<br />

of the economy. Roughly 11 million people live in the region, resulting in a population density that is<br />

low (111 people/km 2 ) compared to the country as a whole (231 people/km 2 ). Roughly half the<br />

population is a member of an ethnic minority, compared to just 12 percent nationally. The region is<br />

less urbanized <strong>and</strong> more dependent on the agricultural sector than other regions of Vietnam. And the<br />

incidence of poverty is probably highest in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, though some studies rank the North<br />

Central Coast <strong>and</strong> the Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s as equally poor.<br />

Nonetheless, there is considerable diversify across the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. The topography is<br />

highest <strong>and</strong> most rugged in Lai Chau, Lao Cai, <strong>and</strong> Son La, while provinces adjacent to the Red River<br />

Delta have significant lowl<strong>and</strong> areas. The infrastructure is better <strong>and</strong> the population density is much<br />

higher in the provinces near the Delta such as Thai Nguyen, Bac Giang, <strong>and</strong> Phu Tho. Although<br />

ethnic minorities dominate in most of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, Kinh are the main ethnic group in large<br />

areas of Thai Nguyen, Bac Giang, Phu Tho, <strong>and</strong> Quang Ninh. The level of urbanization varies from 7<br />

percent in Bac Giang to 44 percent in Quang Ninh,. Similarly, the incidence of poverty varies widely,<br />

being greatest in the border provinces such as Lai Chau, Ha Giang, <strong>and</strong> Son La <strong>and</strong> lowest in Quang<br />

Ninh <strong>and</strong> provinces adjacent to the Delta.<br />

Page 37


Chapter 2. Background on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region<br />

Some general trends in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s can be identified by comparing statistics for<br />

1995 <strong>and</strong> 2000. Although the agricultural sector is growing rapidly (6 percent per year), the<br />

agricultural share of GDP has fallen from 47 percent to 42 percent over this period, indicating that<br />

non-agricultural diversification is occurring at the regional level. The area allocated to rice has been<br />

almost unchanged over this period, but rice production per capita has grown significantly due to rising<br />

yields <strong>and</strong>, to a lesser extent, cropping intensification. At the same time, there is evidence of crop<br />

diversification in that the share of crop l<strong>and</strong> allocated to non-rice crops <strong>and</strong> non-food crops has<br />

increased by 5-6 percentage points. Finally, the growth in agricultural GDP per hectare suggests a<br />

trend of diversification into higher-value crops <strong>and</strong> other agricultural activities. These trends, <strong>and</strong><br />

their impact on living st<strong>and</strong>ards, are discussed in the next chapter.<br />

Page 38


CHAPTER THREE<br />

PATTERNS AND TRENDS IN DIVERSIFICATION:<br />

ANALYSIS OF THREE NATIONAL HOUSEHOLD SURVEYS<br />

3.1 Introduction<br />

Between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998, rural poverty fell from 66 percent to 45 percent (Joint Government-<br />

World Bank-NGO Working Group, 2000). Part of the reduction in poverty is due to higher yields of<br />

rice <strong>and</strong> other crops, which have allowed Vietnam to become the second largest rice exporter with no<br />

expansion in rice area <strong>and</strong> no reduction in domestic consumption (Minot <strong>and</strong> Goletti, 2000). In<br />

addition, Vietnamese farmers have diversified into higher-value crops. Vietnam has become the<br />

second largest coffee producer in the world, <strong>and</strong> production <strong>and</strong> export of fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables have<br />

risen dramatically over this period. And part of the income growth <strong>and</strong> poverty reduction is<br />

undoubtedly due to diversification into non-crop activities such as aquaculture, livestock raising, <strong>and</strong><br />

non-farm activities.<br />

The importance of each of these factors in rural income growth <strong>and</strong> poverty reduction has<br />

implications for policy <strong>and</strong> public investment. If most income growth comes from technological<br />

change which increases yields, then investments in agricultural research deserve priority 1 . If income<br />

growth derives largely from crop diversification, then research into the constraint that prevent some<br />

farmers from diversifying deserves greater attention. And if income growth or poverty rises mostly<br />

due to the switch to non-farm activities, then non-farm employment generation should be the focus of<br />

research.<br />

Furthermore, the most important factor in raising rural incomes may be different than the<br />

most important factor in reducing rural poverty. For example, it may be that low-income households<br />

benefit more from higher yields <strong>and</strong> crop diversification, while higher-income households gain with<br />

diversification into non-farm activities. The latter effect could dominate the increase in average rural<br />

income, while the former would have a larger impact on the incidence of poverty.<br />

Finally, it is possible that the importance of each factor will vary depending on household<br />

characteristics <strong>and</strong> location. For example, yield increases may be more important for farmers in<br />

irrigated lowl<strong>and</strong> areas, crop diversification may be important to household near roads <strong>and</strong> market<br />

infrastructure, <strong>and</strong> diversification into non-farm activities to be important near urban areas.<br />

In light of the rapid growth in rural income in Vietnam <strong>and</strong> the lack of information on the<br />

sources of growth, this study will focus on the following questions:<br />

1<br />

In theory, investment decisions should be made based on the size of the marginal contribution to<br />

growth from alternative investments. However, since this information is generally not available, a reasonable<br />

approximation is to allocate investment among growth strategies according to the average contribution to<br />

economic growth.<br />

Page 39


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

• What is the relative importance of various sources of rural income growth in Vietnam:<br />

yield increases, crop price increases, diversification into high-value crops, growth in<br />

livestock <strong>and</strong> aquaculture, or the shift toward non-farm activities.<br />

• What is the relative importance of these factors in the dramatic reduction in rural poverty<br />

in Vietnam<br />

• How do the sources of income growth <strong>and</strong> poverty reduction vary by region <strong>and</strong> by type<br />

of household<br />

3.2 Data <strong>and</strong> methods<br />

What is income diversification <strong>and</strong> how do we measure it Before analyzing the patterns <strong>and</strong><br />

trends in income diversification in the north mountain region of Vietnam, it is important to address<br />

these two questions. In this section, we briefly describe the data used in this section, the definitions of<br />

diversification adopted, <strong>and</strong> the measures of diversification used.<br />

3.2.1 Data<br />

This report uses three national household surveys to examine the patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in<br />

income diversification. The first Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey (VLSS) was carried out in 1992-<br />

93 by the State Planning Committee <strong>and</strong> the General Statistics Office, with financial contributions<br />

from the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) <strong>and</strong> the Swedish International<br />

Development Agency (SIDA) <strong>and</strong> technical assistance from the World Bank. The survey included a<br />

household survey, a community survey, <strong>and</strong> a market price survey. The household survey covered<br />

household size <strong>and</strong> composition, health, anthropometric measures of nutrition, education, housing<br />

characteristics, migration, employment, non-farm enterprises, agriculture, other income, expenditure<br />

<strong>and</strong> food consumption, ownership of consumer durables, <strong>and</strong> savings <strong>and</strong> credit. The household<br />

questionnaire was approximately 110 pages long <strong>and</strong> included about 1000 questions. The sample was<br />

selected in three stages using data from the 1989 Population Census. First, 120 villages <strong>and</strong> 30 urban<br />

precincts were selected at r<strong>and</strong>om, with probabilities proportional to the population. Then two rural<br />

hamlets or urban blocks were selected in each selected village/precinct. Finally, 16 households were<br />

selected in each selected hamlet/block, making a total sample of 4800 households (see SPC/GSO,<br />

1994 for more details). The sample was designed to be representative at the level of the seven<br />

geographic regions of Vietnam. The survey was implemented between October 1992 <strong>and</strong> October<br />

1993. Because the bulk of the data collection took place in 1993, we will refer to it as the 1993 VLSS.<br />

The second Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey was conducted in 1997-98 by the General<br />

Statistics Office, with financial support from the UNDP <strong>and</strong> SIDA <strong>and</strong> technical assistance from the<br />

World Bank. Like the 1993 VLSS, the survey included a household survey, a community survey, <strong>and</strong><br />

a market price survey, though a survey of health centers was added. The household questionnaire<br />

covers the same topics as the 1993 VLSS, with only slight changes in the questions <strong>and</strong> format. The<br />

household sample includes most of the households from the 1993 VLSS, as well as additional<br />

Page 40


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

households to provide better coverage of urban areas <strong>and</strong> the Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s 2 . The sample<br />

contains 6000 households <strong>and</strong> is representative for each of ten strata, the rural areas of the seven<br />

geographic regions <strong>and</strong> three urban strata (Hanoi <strong>and</strong> Ho Chi Minh City, other cities, <strong>and</strong> towns). The<br />

data collection began in December 1997 <strong>and</strong> was completed in December 1998. We will refer to this<br />

survey as the 1998 VLSS.<br />

The Vietnam Household Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey (VHLSS) was carried out in 2002 by the<br />

General Statistics Office with support from the United Nations Development Programme, the Swedish<br />

International Development Agency, the Japan Bank for International Cooperation <strong>and</strong> the World<br />

Bank. The VHLSS has two versions: a small questionnaire (36 pages) administered to about 45,000<br />

households <strong>and</strong> a larger questionnaire (43 pages) administered to a smaller sample of about 30,000.<br />

The larger questionnaire has an expenditure module, allowing calculation of more reliable<br />

expenditure-based estimates of living st<strong>and</strong>ards. In this analysis, we use the data from the first two<br />

rounds of the smaller-sample version because we need expenditure data for comparability with the<br />

two VLSS surveys. The larger VHLSS questionnaire is similar to the VLSS questionnaire except that<br />

some modules are not included (anthropometrics, migration, <strong>and</strong> savings <strong>and</strong> credit) <strong>and</strong> most of the<br />

other modules are simplified. For example, the VHLSS does not collect crop-level information on<br />

seed, fertilizer, <strong>and</strong> other input costs, so it is not possible to calculate net income from each crop.<br />

Table 3-1.summarizes the differences across the three surveys.<br />

Table 3-1. Characteristics of the household surveys<br />

Name<br />

Period of<br />

data<br />

collection<br />

Sample<br />

size<br />

Length of the<br />

household<br />

questionnaire<br />

1993 Vietnam<br />

Living St<strong>and</strong>ards<br />

Survey<br />

1998 Vietnam<br />

Living St<strong>and</strong>ards<br />

Survey<br />

2002 Vietnam<br />

Household<br />

Living St<strong>and</strong>ards<br />

Survey<br />

1992-<br />

1993<br />

1997-<br />

1998<br />

2002<br />

Lowest level of<br />

representativeness<br />

Types of data collected<br />

4800 110 pages Seven regions Household member characteristics,<br />

education, health, employment,<br />

migration, housing, fertility,<br />

agriculture, non-farm selfemployment,<br />

expenditure, assets, other<br />

income, <strong>and</strong> savings <strong>and</strong> credit.<br />

6000 110 pages Ten strata (7 rural<br />

regions <strong>and</strong> 3 types<br />

of urban areas)<br />

30,000 43 pages Urban <strong>and</strong> rural<br />

areas of eight<br />

regions<br />

Almost identical content <strong>and</strong> structure<br />

as the 1992-93 VLSS.<br />

Similar to VLSS but no migration,<br />

anthropometrics, savings, or credit<br />

modules. Other modules simplified<br />

45,000 36 pages 61 provinces Similar to small-sample VHLSS but no<br />

expenditure module.<br />

3.2.2 Calculation of income<br />

<strong>Income</strong> is calculated from both the VLSS <strong>and</strong> the VHLSS as the sum of net revenues from the<br />

following sources: crop production, agricultural by-products, livestock production, aquaculture,<br />

2<br />

Because the 1993 VLSS sample was designed to be proportional to the population, the sample for<br />

the sparsely populated Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s was just 128 households. In the 1998 VLSS, two clusters from the<br />

1993 VLSS sample in the Red River Delta were dropped <strong>and</strong> 1290 households were added, mostly in urban<br />

areas <strong>and</strong> in the Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

Page 41


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

forestry, agricultural processing, non-farm enterprises, wages, transfers, <strong>and</strong> other income. The value<br />

of crop sales is collected directly from the questionnaire. The value of crop production that is<br />

consumed at home is imputed using the reported quantities <strong>and</strong> the regional average sale price for the<br />

commodity in question. Crop production costs, including seed, fertilizer, pesticides, l<strong>and</strong> rental, hired<br />

labor, storage, <strong>and</strong> marketing, are deducted.<br />

Net income from each crop is calculated as the value of production minus the cost of<br />

production. The VLSS questionnaire does not allocate some costs (hired labor, equipment rental, <strong>and</strong><br />

storage), so it was necessary to distribute these costs among the crops in proportion to the value of<br />

production of each crop in each household. In the VHLSS crop input costs are collected at the crop<br />

category level (e.g. food grains), but not at the crop level, so we can calculate net income from crops,<br />

but not the net income from each crop.<br />

Livestock revenue includes the value of animal sales <strong>and</strong> home consumption of meat from<br />

animals minus the value of animal purchases, plus the sales <strong>and</strong> home consumption of animal<br />

products such as milk <strong>and</strong> eggs. The home consumption of animal products is calculated from the<br />

expenditure section of the questionnaire. In the VLSS questionnaire, the expenses associated with<br />

livestock <strong>and</strong> aquaculture production are combined. In order to calculate net revenue from livestock<br />

<strong>and</strong> aquaculture production separately, it was necessary to allocate the costs in proportion to the gross<br />

value of production of livestock <strong>and</strong> aquaculture. In this case, the VHLSS is more detailed, collecting<br />

livestock <strong>and</strong> aquaculture expenses separately.<br />

Aquaculture sales, net of the purchase of breeding stock, were collected directly. A small<br />

number of households in the 1998 VLSS that reported production <strong>and</strong> aquaculture area, but no sales<br />

value. For these households, the sales value was imputed using the national average sales per square<br />

meter of aquaculture area. The home consumption of fish <strong>and</strong> seafood, as measured by the<br />

expenditure section of the questionnaire, was also included. As described above, the VLSS expenses<br />

for livestock <strong>and</strong> aquaculture production were allocated between the two sectors according the<br />

household level gross values. The value of fish caught <strong>and</strong> sold is apparently not collected in the two<br />

VLSS questionnaires (although home consumption of such fish is presumably included in the<br />

expenditure section). The VHLSS is more complete in collecting information on income from both<br />

aquaculture <strong>and</strong> capture fisheries.<br />

Net revenue from self-employment by household members in non-farm enterprises can be<br />

calculated two ways. The VLSS includes detailed questions regarding the gross cash revenue,<br />

consumption of enterprise goods <strong>and</strong> raw materials by household members, <strong>and</strong> costs associated with<br />

the three most important enterprises, as well as simplified questions regarding any other enterprises.<br />

From these data, the net enterprise revenue can be calculated. Alternatively, the VLSS also includes a<br />

question on the amount of money that the household retains from enterprise earnings after paying for<br />

hired labor <strong>and</strong> other business expenses. This figure can be added to consumption of enterprise goods<br />

<strong>and</strong> raw materials by household members to obtain a different estimate of net enterprise revenue. The<br />

Page 42


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

average values of these two measures are similar, but the latter measure had fewer extreme values.<br />

For this reason, we adopt the second measure in the analysis of the VLSS analysis 3 . In the VHLSS,<br />

there is only one way to calculate enterprise income, which is in between the two VLSS methods in<br />

terms of complexity.<br />

Wage income is calculated from the VLSS as the sum of annual earnings in wages <strong>and</strong><br />

bonuses from the main job over the previous seven days, secondary jobs over the previous seven days,<br />

<strong>and</strong> (when they are different) the main job over the previous 12 months <strong>and</strong> secondary jobs over the<br />

previous 12 months. The questionnaire collects information on the number of weeks worked, the<br />

number of days per week, <strong>and</strong> the number of hours per day in order to capture seasonal <strong>and</strong> part-time<br />

wage work. The VHLSS employment module is simpler, collecting information on the income from<br />

the main job over the past 12 months <strong>and</strong> the total income from all other wage employment.<br />

Transfers include both private transfers (gifts <strong>and</strong> remittances) <strong>and</strong> public transfers (payments<br />

from various government programs) over the past 12 months. Other income includes pensions, lottery<br />

winnings, <strong>and</strong> income from renting out l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> property. The VLSS <strong>and</strong> VHLSS questionnaires are<br />

similar in this area. Revenue from the sale of assets such as buildings, vehicles, gold, or jewelry are<br />

not included in our definition of income.<br />

3.2.3 Measurement of diversification<br />

As discussed earlier, the term “income diversification” has been used to describe many<br />

different concepts. In this report, we will focus on three related but distinct definitions of income<br />

diversification: diversification as multiple sources of income, diversification as commercialization,<br />

<strong>and</strong> diversification into high-value activities. Below, we discuss several indicators of each definition.<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> as multiple sources of income:<br />

One definition of income diversification relates to the number of income sources <strong>and</strong> the<br />

balance among them. The Simpson index of diversity is widely used in biology to measure the biodiversity<br />

of an eco-system. The Simpson index of diversity is defined as:<br />

SID = 1− ∑<br />

where P i is the proportion of organisms that are classified in species i. The Simpson index of diversity<br />

can also be interpreted as the probability that two r<strong>and</strong>omly selected organisms will be from the same<br />

species 4 . Joshi et al (2003) adapt the Simpson index to compare crop diversification in several South<br />

Asian countries. Here, we use it to measure income diversity, interpreting Pi as the proportion of<br />

income coming from source i. The value of SID always falls between 0 <strong>and</strong> 1. If there is just one<br />

i<br />

2<br />

P i<br />

3<br />

This method of calculating the net revenue from non-farm enterprise was used by the General<br />

Statistics Office in its analysis of the 1998 VLSS (GSO, 2000: 296).<br />

4<br />

The Simpson Index is closely related to the Hirschman-Hirfendal index of concentration.<br />

Specifically, SID = 1-HH/10000. The Simpson Index is also related to the family of generalized entropy<br />

indices. When the generalized entropy index parameter β=1, it is equivalent to 1-SID.<br />

Page 43


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

source of income, P 1 =1, so SID=0. As the number of sources increases, the shares (P i ) decline, as<br />

does the sum of the squared shares, so that SID approaches 1. If there are k sources of income, then<br />

SID falls between zero <strong>and</strong> 1-1/k.<br />

Another index used in studies of bio-diversity is the Shannon-Weaver index, defined as:<br />

SW<br />

= −∑<br />

i<br />

P<br />

i<br />

ln(Pi<br />

)<br />

where P i is defined as above. The Shannon-Weaver index is less sensitive than the Simpson index to<br />

the degree of dominance of the largest categories.<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> as commercialization<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> is sometimes defined as the process of switching from subsistence production<br />

of staple crops to commercial production of a wider range of agricultural commodities <strong>and</strong> to nonfarm<br />

activities. We can identify three measures of commercial diversification. The first measure,<br />

“crop commercialization,” will be defined as the proportion of the value of crop production that is<br />

sold or bartered. The second, “agricultural commercialization,” is defined as the share of agricultural<br />

output (including crops, livestock, fisheries, <strong>and</strong> forestry) that is sold or bartered. The third measure<br />

is “income commercialization,” defined as the proportion of gross income that is in the form of cash<br />

income. Subsistence production is dominated by food, so income commercialization is roughly equal<br />

to the marketed share of agricultural production multiplied by the share of agriculture in total net<br />

income 5 .<br />

High- value diversification<br />

Finally, diversification is often used to refer to the process by which farmers switch from lowvalue<br />

crops <strong>and</strong> activities to higher-value crops <strong>and</strong> activities. Three measures of diversification into<br />

high-value activities are the share of area or income from high-value crops, the percentage of income<br />

from non-crop activities (including livestock, fisheries, <strong>and</strong> forestry) <strong>and</strong> the percentage of income<br />

from non-farm activities (wage income <strong>and</strong> non-farm enterprise income).<br />

Table 3-2: Definitions <strong>and</strong> measures of diversification<br />

Definition of diversification<br />

Measures of diversification<br />

Number of sources of income<br />

Multiple sources of income<br />

Simpson index of diversity<br />

Shannon-Weaver index<br />

Share of crop output that is sold<br />

Commercial orientation<br />

Share of agricultural output that is sold<br />

Share of net income that is in monetary form<br />

5<br />

The VLSS surveys collect information on the home consumption of goods or raw materials from a<br />

household non-farm enterprise. The average value of this non-agricultural home consumption is small,<br />

however, relative to agricultural home consumption.<br />

Page 44


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

High-value activities<br />

Share of area or income from high-value crops<br />

Share of income from non-crop activities<br />

Share of income from non-farm activities<br />

3.2.4 Measuring the contribution of diversification to income growth<br />

The measures of diversification discussed above are static measures in that they quantify the<br />

degree of income diversification at one point in time. We are also interested in measuring the process<br />

of diversification over time. In particular, we would like to measure the contribution of<br />

diversification to income growth. If we simply calculate the average value of crop production per<br />

hectare at two points in time, we are including the effect of price changes <strong>and</strong> yield changes to income<br />

growth. Thus, in order to assess the contribution of diversification, it is necessary to develop a way of<br />

decomposing income growth into various components, one of which is diversification.<br />

We can measure the contribution of income diversification to income growth by decomposing<br />

growth into increases in crop income <strong>and</strong> increases in other income, then separating crop income<br />

growth into four components: changes in yield, changes in real prices, changes in total area sown, <strong>and</strong><br />

crop diversification, where crop diversification is the effect of reallocating l<strong>and</strong> among crops on<br />

income, holding prices, yields, <strong>and</strong> total area constant.<br />

We start with an expression for total net revenue in terms of crop income <strong>and</strong> non-crop<br />

income. Crop income can be rewritten as the product of the area planted, the average yield, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

average value per kilogram. Area, in turn, can be divided up into total area <strong>and</strong> the shares allocated to<br />

each crop:<br />

R =<br />

⎛<br />

⎜<br />

⎝<br />

∑ A<br />

⎜ ⎟<br />

iYi<br />

Pi<br />

+ NCY = ∑ a iYi<br />

Pi<br />

∑ A i +<br />

i<br />

where R = crop revenue expressed in Vietnamese dong per year per household<br />

Y i = yield of crop i expressed in kilograms per sown hectare<br />

P i = real net income from crop i per unit of output expressed in Vietnamese dong per kilogram<br />

A i = sown area of crop i expressed in hectares (double cropped l<strong>and</strong> is counted twice)<br />

a = share of crop area allocated to crop i<br />

NCY = non-crop income expressed in Vietnamese dong per year per household<br />

Next, we take the total derivative of both sides:<br />

⎛<br />

dR ≅ ⎜<br />

⎜<br />

⎝<br />

∑<br />

i<br />

i<br />

⎞<br />

⎟<br />

⎠<br />

i<br />

NCY<br />

⎞ ⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞<br />

a Y P ⎟d⎜<br />

A ⎟<br />

i i i<br />

i + ⎜ A ⎟<br />

i d⎜<br />

a iYi<br />

P ⎟<br />

i + dNCY<br />

⎟ ⎜∑<br />

⎟ ⎜∑<br />

⎟ ⎜∑<br />

⎟<br />

⎠ ⎝ i ⎠ ⎝ i ⎠ ⎝ i ⎠<br />

The second term on the right-h<strong>and</strong> side can changed from the change in a sum to the sum of changes:<br />

⎛<br />

dR ≅ ⎜<br />

⎜<br />

⎝<br />

∑<br />

i<br />

⎞ ⎛ ⎞<br />

a Y P ⎟d⎜<br />

A ⎟<br />

i i i<br />

i + A i d(a iYi<br />

Pi<br />

) + dNCY<br />

⎟ ⎜∑<br />

⎟ ∑ ∑<br />

⎠ ⎝ i ⎠ i i<br />

Page 45


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

⎛<br />

dR ≅ ⎜<br />

⎜<br />

⎝<br />

∑<br />

i<br />

⎞ ⎛<br />

a i Yi<br />

P ⎟<br />

i d⎜<br />

⎟ ⎜<br />

⎠ ⎝<br />

+<br />

∑<br />

i<br />

∑<br />

i<br />

A<br />

i<br />

A<br />

⎞<br />

⎟ +<br />

⎟<br />

⎠<br />

i<br />

∑<br />

i<br />

∑<br />

i<br />

A<br />

Y P da<br />

i<br />

i<br />

i<br />

∑<br />

i<br />

i<br />

a Y dP +<br />

i<br />

+ dNCY<br />

i<br />

i<br />

∑<br />

i<br />

A<br />

i<br />

∑<br />

i<br />

a P dY<br />

The five terms on the right-h<strong>and</strong> side of the equation can be described as follows:<br />

i<br />

i<br />

i<br />

• The first term on the right side represents the change in crop revenue due to the change in<br />

total area allocated to crops. The expression ΣaYP is the weighted average revenue per<br />

hectare, where the weights are the proportion of total area allocated to each crop (a i ).<br />

• The second term on the right side is the change in gross crop revenue attributable to the<br />

change in real prices of the crops. The first summation is the total area, while the second<br />

represents the change in average gross revenue per hectare due to price changes.<br />

• The third term is the change in gross crop revenue due to changes in yields. The first<br />

summation is the total area, while the second is the change in average gross revenue per<br />

hectare due to yield increases.<br />

• The fourth term on the right side represents the change in agricultural revenue due to crop<br />

diversification, that is, the shift in the allocation of l<strong>and</strong> among crops. Again, the first<br />

summation is the total area, while the second is the change in average gross revenue due<br />

to shifts in the allocation of l<strong>and</strong> among the crops. This fourth term will be zero if there is<br />

no reallocation of l<strong>and</strong> among crops (da i = 0 for all crops). It will also be zero if the<br />

revenue per hectare is the same for all crops, since Σda i = 0.<br />

• And the fifth term is simply the change in non-crop income. Non-crop activities can be<br />

further disaggregated into livestock activities, fishery activities (including aquaculture),<br />

forestry, wages, non-farm enterprise activities, transfers, <strong>and</strong> other income. These<br />

different terms have been combined to simplify the exposition.<br />

Thus, the contribution of crop diversification to overall growth in crop income is measured by<br />

calculating the income change that would occur if cropl<strong>and</strong> were reallocated among crops the way it<br />

actually was between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998, but yield, prices, <strong>and</strong> total area remained constant. Dividing<br />

both sides of the equation by the overall change in income (dR) will give the proportional contribution<br />

of each component to overall growth. Naturally, this decomposition can be carried out for any region,<br />

income group, or any other category of households.<br />

Unfortunately, this analysis cannot be carried out to explain growth in rural income between<br />

1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002 because the 2002 VHLSS does not provide information on input use for each crop 6 .<br />

Thus, it is not possible to calculate net income for each crop (P i ), which is necessary for the analysis.<br />

In interpreting the results, there are three qualifications that should be kept in mind. First, the<br />

decomposition is only approximate because there is an interaction term that reflects, for example, the<br />

effect of higher yields on the additional area planted. As a result, the sum of the percentage changes<br />

6<br />

The VHLSS does collect information on the value of each type of input used for each crop category,<br />

such as grains <strong>and</strong> industrial crops, but not for each crop, such as rice or tea.<br />

Page 46


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

will generally be somewhat less than or somewhat greater than 100 percent. In some cases, when one<br />

of the factors changes by a large percentage, the discrepancy can be large.<br />

Second, as mentioned in Section 3.2.2, the VLSS questionnaire does not link some inputs<br />

(hired labor, equipment rental, <strong>and</strong> storage costs) to a specific crop, so these costs are allocated in<br />

proportion to the value of output. Furthermore, the VLSS does not provide information on the cost of<br />

planting tree crops unless they were planted in the year of the survey.<br />

Third, for fruit trees <strong>and</strong> industrial tree crops, the VLSS gives respondents the choice of<br />

expressing the total area <strong>and</strong> the productive area in hectares or in the number of trees. Since the<br />

decomposition of crop income relies on area estimates in hectares, we need to impute the area of tree<br />

crops for households that only gave the number of trees. This was done by estimating the average<br />

yield (output per hectare of productive l<strong>and</strong>) based on the responses of those who gave area figures in<br />

hectares. For farms that only gave the number of trees, the productive area in hectares was calculated<br />

by dividing household output by the average yield for that crop <strong>and</strong> that region (or using a national<br />

average yield if necessary). With information on the productive area <strong>and</strong> the productive number of<br />

trees, the unproductive area was imputed from the number of unproductive trees, assuming that the<br />

tree density was the same for productive <strong>and</strong> unproductive areas.<br />

The next section describes the importance of different sources of income among rural<br />

households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s based on the 2002 Vietnam Household Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey.<br />

In subsequent sections, we describe the patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification based on a comparison<br />

of the 1993 VLSS, the 1998 VLSS, <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

3.3 Changes in st<strong>and</strong>ard of living in rural areas<br />

We begin our description of the results of the VLSS analysis by comparing the material<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard of living of rural Vietnamese households in 1993, 1998, <strong>and</strong> 2002. Two measures of<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard of living are used: per capita consumption expenditure <strong>and</strong> per capita net income. Per capita<br />

expenditure is defined as the sum of purchases on consumption goods, the value of food produced by<br />

the household for home consumption, <strong>and</strong> the rental value of consumer durables <strong>and</strong> housing. These<br />

variables were calculated by the team of analysts at the GSO <strong>and</strong> the World Bank that first processed<br />

the results of each survey. The expenditure variables are constructed to be comparable with each<br />

other 7 . Per capita net income was calculated for this report, as described earlier (see Section 3.2.2 in<br />

this chapter). Both are expressed in constant Vietnamese dong at prices of January 2002.<br />

The results confirm that the rapid economic growth recorded in national accounts has<br />

translated into concrete gains for rural households. Between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998, estimated per capita<br />

expenditure in rural areas rose 32 percent, while estimated per capita income in rural areas rose 79<br />

7<br />

Some minor types of expenditure were excluded from the 1998 VLSS analysis because data on those<br />

expenditures had not been collected as part of the 1993 VLSS.<br />

Page 47


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

percent (see Table 3-3 <strong>and</strong> Table 3-4). It is not clear whether the higher estimated income growth<br />

reflects reality or not. 8 . Between 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002, the increases in income <strong>and</strong> expenditure were both<br />

11 percent, smaller but still significant. The slower growth in the latter period may reflect lower<br />

world commodity prices, particularly for rice <strong>and</strong> coffee, but more likely it is a reflection of<br />

differences in the sample <strong>and</strong> questionnaire between the two VLSS surveys <strong>and</strong> the VHLSS.<br />

Table 3-3.<br />

Summary changes in expenditure for rural households<br />

Per capita expenditure<br />

Percentage change<br />

1993 1998 2002 1993-1998 1998-2002<br />

--(1000 VND/year)-- (percent)<br />

Sex of household<br />

Male 1,837 2,429 2,689 32 11<br />

Female 2,053 2,703 3,093 32 14<br />

Ethnicity<br />

Kinh/Hoa 1,972 2,637 2,921 34 11<br />

Minority 1,363 1,704 1,807 25 6<br />

Expenditure Category<br />

Poorest 930 1,206 1,240 30 3<br />

2 1,341 1,774 1,837 32 4<br />

3 1,724 2,297 2,444 33 6<br />

4 2,271 3,155 3,431 39 9<br />

Richest 3,866 5,432 6,466 41 19<br />

Region<br />

North Upl<strong>and</strong> 1,529 2,008 2,238 31 11<br />

Red River Delta 1,759 2,560 2,791 46 9<br />

North Central Coast 1,616 2,342 2,502 45 7<br />

South Central Coast 1,988 2,462 2,923 24 19<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong> 1,751 2,231 2,057 27 -8<br />

Southeast 2,475 3,909 3,132 58 -20<br />

Mekong River Delta 2,250 2,530 3,173 12 25<br />

All rural areas 1,886 2,488 2,771 32 11<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS. Values are expressed in constant prices of January 2002.<br />

Female-headed households do not seem to be disadvantaged, either in terms of the level of<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard of living or in terms of participation in the gains from economic growth. If anything, femaleheaded<br />

households may be somewhat better off, at least in terms of material well-being.<br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong>, both income <strong>and</strong> expenditure data indicate that ethnic minorities are<br />

considerably poorer than the majority Kinh/Hoa. The expenditure data (which are probably more<br />

reliable) suggest that the st<strong>and</strong>ard of living of ethnic minorities is 31-39 percent below that of<br />

Kinh/Hoa households <strong>and</strong> that it has risen but more slowly than that of Kinh/Hoa households.<br />

8<br />

One possibility is that incomes have increased more rapidly than expenditure, implying a large<br />

increase in household savings <strong>and</strong>/or investment. A second possibility is that these results are accurate for the<br />

years of the survey, but reflect annual volatility in income rather than a trend. A third possibility is sampling or<br />

non-sampling error contribute to this discrepancy. It should be noted that income <strong>and</strong> expenditure were not<br />

constructed to match each other. For example, expenditure includes the rental equivalent of housing <strong>and</strong><br />

consumer durables because it was designed to measure the st<strong>and</strong>ard of living, but income excludes this<br />

component because the purpose was to focus on sources of income. Thus, it is not possible to interpret<br />

differences between income <strong>and</strong> expenditure as savings.<br />

Page 48


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Table 3-4. Summary changes in income for rural households<br />

Per capita income<br />

Percentage change<br />

1993 1998 2002 1993-1998 1998-2002<br />

--(1000 VND/year)-- --percent--<br />

Sex of household<br />

Male 1,565 2,801 3,113 79 11<br />

Female 1,622 2,913 3,477 80 19<br />

Ethnicity<br />

Kinh/Hoa 1,641 3,013 3,399 84 13<br />

Minority 1,197 1,833 2,286 53 25<br />

Expenditure Category<br />

Poorest 970 1,359 1,640 40 21<br />

2 1,122 2,159 2,417 92 12<br />

3 1,624 2,787 3,112 72 12<br />

4 1,832 3,688 4,426 101 20<br />

Richest 3,178 5,909 6,968 86 18<br />

Region<br />

North Upl<strong>and</strong> 1,474 2,252 2,708 53 20<br />

Red River Delta 1,593 2,618 3,110 64 19<br />

North Central Coast 1,172 2,375 2,711 103 14<br />

South Central Coast 1,142 2,474 3,081 117 24<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong> 1,318 3,104 2,493 136 -20<br />

Southeast 2,163 3,978 3,715 84 -7<br />

Mekong River Delta 1,946 3,186 4,414 64 30<br />

All rural areas 1,578 2,825 3,176 79 12<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS. Values are expressed in constant prices of January 2002.<br />

If we divide the sample for each year into expenditure quintiles 9 , then the growth in per capita<br />

expenditure is higher for the richer quintiles. The patterns for income are less clear, but growth in per<br />

capita income over 1993-98 for the poorest quintile is 40 percent, while the growth in the other four<br />

quintiles ranges from 72 to 101 percent. These results indicate that the gap between rich <strong>and</strong> poor is<br />

widening, even though the st<strong>and</strong>ard of living of the poor is rising.<br />

The regional results also show some divergence. According to expenditure data, the<br />

households in the Southeast have gained the most over the 1993-98 period (58 percent growth), while<br />

those in the Mekong Delta have gained the least (12 percent), but the pattern is reversed over 1998-<br />

2002. According to both income <strong>and</strong> expenditure data, households in the Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s had<br />

positive growth over 1993-98 <strong>and</strong> negative growth in 1998-2002, probably reflecting the initial<br />

expansion in coffee production <strong>and</strong> subsequent decline in coffee prices, respectively. The Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s experienced average growth in per capita expenditure over both periods. It should be kept in<br />

mind that the in-migration of poor households into a region will lower the average growth rate. The<br />

negative growth in the Southeast <strong>and</strong> Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s over 1998-2002, to the extent that it is<br />

accurate, may be the result of this phenomenon.<br />

9<br />

The expenditure categories are defined in terms of national quintiles for that year. For example, the<br />

first quintile in the 1993 data includes rural households that were below the 20 th percentile nationally in 1993.<br />

Because the quintiles are defined nationally, each quintile will not necessarily represent 20 percent of the rural<br />

population. Because the quintiles are defined for each year, expenditure ranges for each quintile vary across<br />

years.<br />

Page 49


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

3.4 Sources of income in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

How do rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> earn their living This section describes the<br />

different economic activities carried out by these households as an introduction to the analysis of<br />

income diversification in the following sections. The results are from the first two rounds of the<br />

“small sample” of the 2002 VHLSS. This sample include 15,019 households nationally <strong>and</strong> 2,780<br />

households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. Unless otherwise specified, all income figures in this chapter<br />

refer to average net income adjusted to January 2002 prices <strong>and</strong> including zeroes for households that<br />

do not earn income from the source in question.<br />

Virtually all rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s (100 percent of the sample) have some<br />

crop production, <strong>and</strong> it accounts for 38 percent of net household income. Livestock production is also<br />

carried out by almost all rural households, but its contribution to net income is smaller (13 percent).<br />

Less than half (45 percent) have wage income, but on average it contributes 16 percent of net<br />

income. About one-third of rural households have enterprise income, defined as income from selfemployment<br />

in small businesses. Three-quarters of rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s receive<br />

transfers, including gifts, remittances, <strong>and</strong> assistance from the government (see Table 3-5)<br />

Table 3-5. Importance of different sources of net income among rural households<br />

in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s in 2002<br />

Share of<br />

households<br />

Share of<br />

earning Net income net income<br />

Crops 100 4,939 38<br />

Livestock 97 1,657 13<br />

Fisheries 37 256 2<br />

Forestry 81 986 8<br />

Enterprise 35 1,324 10<br />

Wages 45 2,009 16<br />

Transfers 76 1,507 11<br />

Other 25 229 2<br />

Total - 12,907 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

Looking more closely at crop income, the most widespread crops are rice (grown by 91<br />

percent of the rural households), maize (62 percent), water morning glory (58 percent), cassava (49<br />

percent), <strong>and</strong> bananas (47 percent). In value terms, rice is the most important crop, accounting for 46<br />

percent of the total net value of crop production, followed by maize (15 percent). Tea, cassava, <strong>and</strong><br />

litchi/ longan/ rambuttan, each account for 5-7 percent of the value of crop production (see Table 3-6).<br />

Page 50


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Table 3-6. Importance of different crops in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, 2002<br />

Crop Share of Net income Percent of<br />

households from crop net income<br />

growing<br />

from crops<br />

Rice 91 2,267 46<br />

Maize 62 749 15<br />

Sweet potatoes 31 54 1<br />

Potatoes 6 19 0<br />

Cassava 49 228 5<br />

Other staple crops 5 17 0<br />

Kohlrabi, cabbage, cauliflower 43 80 2<br />

Other leafy greens 61 91 2<br />

Tomatoes 6 11 0<br />

Water morning glory 58 43 1<br />

Fresh legumes 33 43 1<br />

Other vegetables 60 92 2<br />

Soybeans 38 90 2<br />

Peanuts 27 61 1<br />

Sugar cane 7 78 2<br />

Tobacco 2 14 0<br />

Other annual crops 5 9 1<br />

Tea 20 363 7<br />

Other industrial tree crops 1 3 0<br />

Citrus 21 36 1<br />

Pineapple 6 9 0<br />

Bananas 47 76 2<br />

Mango 7 10 0<br />

Apple 4 3 0<br />

Plum 8 7 0<br />

Papaya 15 10 0<br />

Litchi, longan & rambuttan 18 265 5<br />

Custard apple 10 14 0<br />

Jackfruit, durian 13 11 0<br />

Other fruit trees 7 9 1<br />

Straw/thatch 37 41 1<br />

Sweet potato leaves & stems 23 22 0<br />

Stems of cassava tree 25 15 0<br />

Legume leaves <strong>and</strong> stems 12 4 0<br />

Sugar cane by-products 2 3 0<br />

Stems of jute, ramie, etc 1 1 0<br />

Other 8 10 0<br />

Total 100 4,947 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

Almost all rural households in the region (97 percent) also have some income from livestock<br />

activities, although the overall contribution to household income is just 13 percent. Livestock income<br />

can take the form of net sales (sales minus purchases) of animals, sale of animal products, or home<br />

consumption of other animal products. The most common types of animals are poultry (raised by 85<br />

percent of the households) <strong>and</strong> pigs (70 percent). In value terms, pigs, poultry, <strong>and</strong> breeding stock<br />

represent about three-quarters of the livestock income (see Table 3-7).<br />

Page 51


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Table 3-7. Importance of different livestock in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, 2002<br />

Percent of Net income Percent<br />

Animal/product households from each of net income<br />

producing<br />

Buffalo 8 132 8<br />

Pigs 70 388 24<br />

Poultry 85 422 26<br />

Breeding stock 21 399 24<br />

Other cattle 14 43 3<br />

Eggs 75 178 11<br />

Silk worms 1 9 1<br />

Honey 2 15 1<br />

Livestock by-product 23 53 3<br />

Other livestock 2 6 0<br />

Total 97 1,645 100<br />

Source: Analysis of 2002 VHLSS.<br />

With regard to fisheries, over one-third (37 percent) of the rural households in the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s are involved in fisheries, though it accounts for just 2 percent of net household income. Fish<br />

production is much more important than shrimp production (see Table 3-8).<br />

Table 3-8. Importance of different fishery products in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, 2002<br />

Product Percent of Net income Percent<br />

households from each of<br />

catching/<br />

net income<br />

raising<br />

Fish 35 223 69<br />

Shrimp 5 13 4<br />

Other 11 89 27<br />

Total 37 324 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

A large majority of rural households (63 percent) report forestry activity, with collection of<br />

firewood being the most common one <strong>and</strong> the largest in value terms. Bamboo is the most common<br />

tree crop, grown by 16 percent of the region’s rural households. Altogether, these forestry activities<br />

contribute about 8 percent of the total net income of rural households in the region (see Table 3-9).<br />

Table 3-9. Importance of different forestry products in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, 2002<br />

Product Percent of Net income Percent<br />

households from each of net income<br />

producing<br />

Anise tree 1 34 5<br />

Tree foe wood 7 86 11<br />

Bamboo 16 51 7<br />

Pan palm tree 2 9 1<br />

Other sylviculture tree 2 33 3<br />

Firewood 62 541 72<br />

Total 63 754 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

Another source of income is self-employment in non-farm enterprises, usually microenterprises.<br />

The data from the VHLSS indicate that about one-third of the rural households in the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s operate of one or more non-farm enterprise. These household enterprises<br />

contributed about 10 percent of household income. The enterprises tend to be quite varied, <strong>and</strong> no<br />

one type of enterprise accounts for large percentage of the total. The most common types of<br />

enterprises are food processors (including rice milling) <strong>and</strong> retail trade, each type being found in over<br />

Page 52


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

10 percent of the households. In value terms, food processing <strong>and</strong> retail trade account for 61 percent<br />

of the net income generated by these enterprises (see Table 3-10).<br />

Table 3-10. Importance of different types of non-farm enterprises in the rural Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s, 2002<br />

Product Percent of Net income Percent<br />

households with from each of net income<br />

enterprise<br />

Mining 2 86 5<br />

Food processing 13 391 23<br />

Textiles & garments 0 14 1<br />

Wood/bamboo products 5 161 10<br />

Construction 0 5 0<br />

Wholesale trader 1 90 5<br />

Retail trader 13 641 38<br />

Transport services 2 159 10<br />

Rental services 1 30 2<br />

Hunting, trapping etc. 2 4 0<br />

Other 2 82 5<br />

Total 35 1,674 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

<strong>Income</strong> from wages is somewhat more important <strong>and</strong> more widespread compared to<br />

enterprise income. About 45 percent report earning wages, <strong>and</strong> it accounts for 16 percent of<br />

household income. The most common types of wage-paying jobs are in the public sector (including<br />

police), construction, agriculture, <strong>and</strong> mining. Each of these is a source of wage income for at least 6<br />

percent of the rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. The most important wage earning activities<br />

in value terms are in the public sector <strong>and</strong> in construction, though together they account for barely<br />

one-quarter of the total (see Table 3-11).<br />

Table 3-11. Importance of different types of wage income in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, 2002<br />

Type of enterprise Percent Net income Percent<br />

of households from each of value<br />

with income type<br />

Agricultural services 6 91 4<br />

Forestry services 3 76 3<br />

Aquaculture services 2 40 2<br />

Mining 6 186 7<br />

Food processing 2 36 1<br />

Textiles & garments 2 36 1<br />

Wood/bamboo products 4 78 3<br />

Construction 11 275 11<br />

Retail trader 4 98 4<br />

Transport services 4 140 6<br />

Government & police 10 332 13<br />

Education 2 60 3<br />

Health & relief 3 175 7<br />

Other 17 904 36<br />

Total 44 2,527 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 2002 VHLS.<br />

In addition to income from economic activities, households receive income in the form of<br />

transfers from the government, family members, <strong>and</strong> (less frequently) non-governmental<br />

organizations. Three-quarters of the respondent reported receiving transfers of one kind or another,<br />

though the true percentage may be even higher. The most common transfers are remittances <strong>and</strong> gifts,<br />

reported by 71 percent of households. Payments from the social insurance fund, <strong>and</strong> social subsidies<br />

Page 53


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

are less widespread (reported by 9 percent of the households each) but more important in value terms.<br />

Overall, transfers contribute 11 percent of household income, on average (see Table 3-12).<br />

Table 3-12. Importance of different types of transfers in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, 2002<br />

Product Percent of Net Percent<br />

households value of value<br />

Remittances <strong>and</strong> gifts 71 938 62<br />

Social insurance fund 9 113 7<br />

Pension <strong>and</strong> allowances 9 457 30<br />

Total 75 1,508 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

The Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey also collected information on other sources of income,<br />

including the rental of l<strong>and</strong> or property, interest income, <strong>and</strong> lottery winnings. This income is not<br />

common, <strong>and</strong> the value is a very small proportion (2 percent) of the total income.<br />

3.5 <strong>Diversification</strong> as multiple sources of income<br />

In this section, we explore the diversity of income sources of rural households in the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> whether this diversity is increasing or decreasing over time. We consider both the<br />

diversity in broad income categories <strong>and</strong> diversity in crop production.<br />

3.5.1 Diversity in sources of income<br />

In order to examine the diversity of income sources, household income is divided into eight<br />

categories: crop income, livestock income, fisheries income, forestry income, non-farm enterprise<br />

income, wages, transfers, <strong>and</strong> other income. The simplest measure of income diversity is to count the<br />

number of income sources (out of the eight listed here) that a household has. According to the<br />

Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Surveys, rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s had an average of 4.43<br />

sources of income in 1993, 4.53 sources in 1998, <strong>and</strong> 4.97 in 2002. These represent small but<br />

statistically significant increases. Both the Simpson Index of Diversity <strong>and</strong> the Shannon Weaver<br />

index are roughly constant in 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998, but increase markedly in 2002. In other words, rural<br />

households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s show a tendency to increase the number of sources of income <strong>and</strong><br />

the balance of income among sources. As will be shown later, this is largely due to the declining<br />

dominance of crop income. These three indicators tend to increase over time in the other regions of<br />

Vietnam in particular (see Table 3-13).<br />

Page 54


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Table 3-13. Measures of diversity in income sources in rural areas by region<br />

in 1993, 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002<br />

Year <strong>and</strong> Region Number of Simpson Shannonincome<br />

Index of Weaver<br />

sources Diversity Index<br />

1993<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 4.43 0.49 0.89<br />

Red River Delta 4.16 0.48 0.85<br />

North Central Coast 3.57 0.45 0.77<br />

South Central Coast 3.74 0.40 0.69<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s 3.41 0.31 0.54<br />

Southeast 3.36 0.37 0.63<br />

Mekong River Delta 4.31 0.43 0.76<br />

Total 4.02 0.44 0.78<br />

1998<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 4.53 0.49 0.88<br />

Red River Delta 4.50 0.49 0.88<br />

North Central Coast 4.82 0.52 0.96<br />

South Central Coast 4.08 0.47 0.84<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s 3.72 0.36 0.63<br />

Southeast 3.92 0.39 0.68<br />

Mekong River Delta 4.30 0.40 0.73<br />

Total 4.41 0.46 0.83<br />

2002<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 4.97 0.59 1.14<br />

Red River Delta 4.37 0.56 1.02<br />

North Central Coast 4.65 0.59 1.11<br />

South Central Coast 4.49 0.54 1.01<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s 5.21 0.53 1.02<br />

Southeast 4.36 0.48 0.89<br />

Mekong River Delta 4.91 0.52 0.99<br />

Total 4.67 0.55 1.04<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

Comparing the indicators across regions, it is interesting to note that the income sources of<br />

households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s are more diverse than in any other region. This is true whether<br />

we measure diversity by the number of income sources, by the Simpson Index of Diversity, or by the<br />

Shannon-Weaver index. The least diverse livelihood patterns are found in the Southeast (see Table 3-<br />

13). Given that the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s is the poorest region in Vietnam <strong>and</strong> the Southeast is the most<br />

urbanized <strong>and</strong> the least poor, these results are consistent with the idea that diverse rural incomes are<br />

associated with poor households that diversify in order to reduce risks associated with fluctuations in<br />

income from any given source.<br />

Given the regional patterns, we might expect greater income diversity among lower-income<br />

households than among higher-income households. In fact, the pattern is more complex. At low<br />

incomes, income diversity rises with income, while at higher incomes, diversity begins to fall 11 . In<br />

1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998, diversity showed an inverted U-shape, while in 2002 diversity is relatively constant<br />

over the lower quintiles, but drops in the richest quintile. It should be kept in mind, however, than the<br />

number of income sources was 4-5 in almost all categories of households (see Table 3-14).<br />

11<br />

The “income” categories are actually quintiles of per capita consumption expenditure. The<br />

quintiles are defined separately for each year, so that the first quintile has the poorest 20 percent of the<br />

households for that year.<br />

Page 55


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Table 3-14. Measures of diversity in income sources in rural area by expenditure<br />

category in 1993, 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002<br />

Year <strong>and</strong> Number of Simpson Shannon-<br />

Expenditure income Index of Weaver<br />

category sources Diversity Index<br />

1993<br />

Poorest 3.82 0.43 0.74<br />

2 3.92 0.44 0.77<br />

3 4.20 0.46 0.81<br />

4 4.17 0.47 0.82<br />

Richest 4.05 0.42 0.76<br />

Total 4.02 0.44 0.78<br />

1998<br />

Poorest 4.26 0.45 0.81<br />

2 4.51 0.47 0.85<br />

3 4.56 0.48 0.86<br />

4 4.47 0.47 0.84<br />

Richest 4.09 0.43 0.78<br />

Total 4.41 0.46 0.83<br />

2002<br />

Poorest 4.69 0.58 1.08<br />

2 4.65 0.57 1.07<br />

3 4.71 0.56 1.04<br />

4 4.69 0.53 1.00<br />

Richest 4.57 0.50 0.93<br />

Total 4.67 0.55 1.04<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS<br />

Finally, urban households have much less diverse livelihoods than rural households. For<br />

example, in 1998, rural households had an average of 4.4 activities while urban households had just<br />

2.9 activities. Similar patterns can be observed in the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 2002 data <strong>and</strong> for the other two<br />

indicators of income diversity (see Table 3-15). It should be noted, however, that this may be a result<br />

of the way we classified income sources. Agricultural income is divided into four categories (crops,<br />

livestock, fisheries, <strong>and</strong> forestry), while activities that are common in urban areas are grouped in two<br />

categories (non farm enterprise income <strong>and</strong> wage income).<br />

Table 3-15. Measures of diversity in income sources in rural <strong>and</strong> urban areas in<br />

1993, 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002.<br />

Year <strong>and</strong> Number of Simpson Shannonresidence<br />

income Index of Weaver<br />

sources Diversity Index<br />

1993<br />

Rural 4.02 0.44 0.78<br />

Urban 2.90 0.35 0.58<br />

Total 3.79 0.42 0.74<br />

1998<br />

Rural 4.41 0.46 0.83<br />

Urban 2.91 0.33 0.55<br />

Total 4.05 0.43 0.77<br />

2002<br />

Rural 4.67 0.55 1.04<br />

Urban 4.34 0.49 0.90<br />

Total 4.65 0.55 1.03<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 & 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

Page 56


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

3.5.2 Diversity in crop production<br />

Within the agricultural sector, we can measure diversity in terms of the number of different<br />

crops grown. We have calculated the number of crops grown by different types of rural farm<br />

households out of the 45 crops for which there is information in the three surveys (households without<br />

crop production were excluded from these calculations). Among crop producing households in the<br />

rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, the average number of crops grown is over 8. In contrast, the rural average is<br />

5-6 crops. The average number of crops grown is smallest (indicating crop specialization) among<br />

rural households n the Southeast <strong>and</strong> Mekong River Delta. For example, in the Mekong Delta in<br />

2002, the average farm household produced just 2.6 crops (see Table 3-16). This is similar to the<br />

regional patterns observed in the diversity of income sources.<br />

Table 3-16. Measures of diversity in crop production by region in 1993, 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002<br />

Year <strong>and</strong> Region Number of Simpson Index Shannoncrops<br />

grown of diversity Weaver index<br />

1993<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 8.02 0.50 1.06<br />

Red River Delta 6.00 0.33 0.71<br />

North Central Coast 5.77 0.45 0.92<br />

South Central Coast 3.98 0.46 0.65<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s 5.15 0.45 0.83<br />

Southeast 3.29 0.30 0.50<br />

Mekong River Delta 4.27 0.34 0.60<br />

Total 5.55 0.39 0.76<br />

1998<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 8.44 0.56 1.19<br />

Red River Delta 6.22 0.37 0.77<br />

North Central Coast 7.77 0.53 1.13<br />

South Central Coast 4.23 0.40 0.74<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s 4.71 0.37 0.68<br />

Southeast 4.10 0.36 0.62<br />

Mekong River Delta 3.29 0.28 0.43<br />

Total 6.00 0.42 0.84<br />

2002<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 8.17 0.53 1.13<br />

Red River Delta 4.70 0.28 0.59<br />

North Central Coast 6.60 0.45 0.96<br />

South Central Coast 3.56 0.30 0.58<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s 6.50 0.42 0.84<br />

Southeast 3.04 0.30 0.51<br />

Mekong River Delta 2.58 0.18 0.30<br />

Total 5.06 0.34 0.69<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 VLSS, the 1998 VLSS, <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

Looking at cropping patterns across income groups, it is apparent that the number of crops<br />

declines among high-income farm households. For example, in 2002 the poorest quintile grows an<br />

average of 5.7 crops, while the richest grows 3.8 crops. It is paradoxical that within each year, the<br />

number of crops declines with income, yet between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998, a period during which rural<br />

incomes rose significantly, the number of crops grown appears to have increased. Perhaps poor<br />

farmers grow a wide variety of crops to meet household needs <strong>and</strong> reduce production risk while<br />

higher income farmers a somewhat more likely to specialize, but both groups have responded to<br />

market liberalization <strong>and</strong> more secure l<strong>and</strong> tenure by trying to grow new crops (Table 3-17).<br />

Page 57


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Table 3-17. Measures of diversity in crop production by expenditure<br />

category in 1993, 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002<br />

Year <strong>and</strong> Number of Simpson Index Shannon-Weaver<br />

expenditure crops grown of diversity index<br />

1993<br />

Poorest 5.35 0.39 0.76<br />

2 5.96 0.41 0.80<br />

3 5.92 0.40 0.78<br />

4 5.32 0.38 0.73<br />

Richest 4.91 0.38 0.71<br />

Total 5.55 0.39 0.76<br />

1998<br />

Poorest 6.38 0.48 0.97<br />

2 6.34 0.43 0.87<br />

3 5.85 0.40 0.80<br />

4 5.66 0.39 0.75<br />

Richest 5.52 0.40 0.77<br />

Total 6.00 0.42 0.84<br />

2002<br />

Poorest 5.73 0.41 0.84<br />

2 5.44 0.36 0.74<br />

3 5.00 0.32 0.65<br />

4 4.47 0.29 0.58<br />

Richest 3.80 0.27 0.52<br />

Total 5.06 0.34 0.69<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 VLSS, the 1998 VLSS, <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

3.6 <strong>Diversification</strong> as commercialization<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> is sometimes defined as the process of switching from food crops for own<br />

consumption to producing goods <strong>and</strong> services for sale. In this section, we examine patterns <strong>and</strong><br />

trends in commercialization using three indicators.<br />

• Crop commercialization is defined as the value of crop sales divided by the gross value of<br />

crop production.<br />

• Agricultural commercialization is defined as the sales of crops, animal products, fish, <strong>and</strong><br />

forest products divided by the gross value of production of crops, livestock, fisheries, <strong>and</strong><br />

forest products.<br />

• <strong>Income</strong> commercialization is defined as the value of sales of farm <strong>and</strong> non-farm products<br />

services divided by the gross value of farm <strong>and</strong> non-farm production.<br />

In each case, the numerator refers only to monetary income, while the denominator includes both<br />

monetary income <strong>and</strong> the value of non-cash income.<br />

Table 3-18 shows the three measures of commercialization by region for 1993, 1998, <strong>and</strong><br />

2002. Rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s sell a relatively small portion of their crop output,<br />

just 34 percent in value terms based on the 2002 VHLSS. The commercial share of crop production<br />

in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s is similar to the share in the Red River Delta <strong>and</strong> the North Central Coast. In<br />

contrast, the marketed share of crop production is over 70 percent in the Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s, the<br />

Southeast, <strong>and</strong> the Mekong Delta 12 .<br />

12<br />

These percentages are calculated as the sum of sales divided by the sum of output, giving greater<br />

weight to households with greater output. If the percentage is calculated as the average of the household-level<br />

Page 58


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Because non-crop agricultural production (livestock, aquaculture, <strong>and</strong> forestry) <strong>and</strong> non-farm<br />

income tend to be more commercial, the marketed share of agricultural output <strong>and</strong> total income is<br />

almost always greater than the marketed share of crop output. Thus, about half the agricultural output<br />

of the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s is marketed <strong>and</strong> over two-thirds of total income is in the form of cash,<br />

according to the 2002 VHLSS. The southern regions tend to be even more commercially oriented.<br />

About 85 percent of the agricultural output of the Southeast <strong>and</strong> Mekong Delta is marketed, as is 90<br />

percent of the income in these regions.<br />

In general, rural households are becoming more commercialized over time. For example, the<br />

marketed share of crop production in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s has increased from 22 percent in<br />

1993 to 34 percent in 2002 (though most of this increase occurred in the 1993-98 period). For the<br />

country as a whole, the share rose from 40 percent in 1993 to 61 percent in 2002. The fact that the<br />

marketed share of crop output in the Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s fell between 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002 may reflect the<br />

drop in the world prices of coffee, reducing the value of sales relative to subsistence food crop<br />

production (see Table 3-18 <strong>and</strong> Figure 3-1).<br />

Table 3-18. Measures of commercialization by region in 1993, 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002<br />

Year <strong>and</strong> Region<br />

Share of output that is sold<br />

Crop Agricultural Total<br />

output output income<br />

(percent) (percent) (percent)<br />

1993<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 22 36 68<br />

Red River Delta 23 39 81<br />

North Central Coast 22 37 74<br />

South Central Coast 23 39 85<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s 78 77 92<br />

Southeast 65 69 93<br />

Mekong River Delta 56 59 88<br />

Total 40 48 84<br />

1998<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 33 44 75<br />

Red River Delta 29 45 88<br />

North Central Coast 30 44 80<br />

South Central Coast 46 55 86<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s 78 78 88<br />

Southeast 77 79 95<br />

Mekong River Delta 74 74 91<br />

Total 54 59 87<br />

2002<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s 34 52 71<br />

Red River Delta 34 61 83<br />

North Central Coast 38 63 82<br />

South Central Coast 53 73 91<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s 74 74 80<br />

Southeast 88 84 89<br />

Mekong River Delta 84 85 91<br />

Total 61 70 84<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

percentages, the marketed share is smaller. For example, the marketed share of crop production in Vietnam in<br />

2002 would be 43 percent using this method of calculation, rather than 61 percent as reported in the table.<br />

Page 59


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Figure 3-1. Share of crop output sold by region <strong>and</strong> by year<br />

Share of crop output sold (%)<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Red River Delta<br />

North Central Coast<br />

South Central Coast<br />

Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Southeast<br />

2002<br />

1998<br />

1993<br />

Mekong River Delta<br />

Vietnam<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS<br />

Looking at the patterns of commercialization across income categories, it is evident that<br />

commercialization is higher among higher income rural households. For example, the share of crop<br />

production that is commercialized rises from 40 percent among the poorest rural households to 79<br />

percent among the highest income category, according to the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

The rise in commercialization over time appears to occur at all income levels. Even the<br />

poorest rural households have experienced an increased degree of crop commercialization between<br />

1993 <strong>and</strong> 2002. In fact, the proportional increase in crop commercialization is similar between the<br />

poorest quintile <strong>and</strong> the richest quintile. These results contradict the view that the poor are being left<br />

behind by the market reforms <strong>and</strong> resulting economic growth. While it is true that the poor participate<br />

less in the market economy compared to the rich, their degree of commercialization is rising as much<br />

as that of their higher income neighbors (Table 3-19).<br />

Page 60


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Table 3-19. Measure of commercialization by expenditure quintile<br />

in 1993, 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002<br />

Year <strong>and</strong><br />

Share of output that is sold<br />

expenditure Crop Agricultural Total<br />

category output output income<br />

(percent) (percent) (percent)<br />

1993<br />

Poorest 29 38 72<br />

2 31 42 74<br />

3 39 48 82<br />

4 44 52 86<br />

Richest 56 61 92<br />

Total 40 48 84<br />

1998<br />

Poorest 37 44 69<br />

2 47 54 79<br />

3 52 57 84<br />

4 62 67 89<br />

Richest 72 74 96<br />

Total 54 59 87<br />

2002<br />

Poorest 40 54 70<br />

2 52 64 78<br />

3 62 71 83<br />

4 70 77 89<br />

Richest 79 84 93<br />

Total 61 70 84<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 & 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

3.7 <strong>Diversification</strong> as shift to high-value activities<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> is sometimes defined as the process of shifting from low-value activities, such<br />

as production of staple food crops, to higher-value activities, including production of higher-value<br />

crops, animal products, fishery products, or non-farm employment. High-value crops are often<br />

defined in terms of the value of the commodity per kilogram. For example, the producer prices of<br />

cassava averaged 500 Vietnamese dong (VND) per kilogram <strong>and</strong> rice, maize, <strong>and</strong> sweet potatoes<br />

averaged 1,350-1,460 VND/kg, according to farm sales recorded in the 1998 VLSS 13 . By contrast,<br />

the average producer price for soybeans, peanuts, tobacco, <strong>and</strong> coffee was over 4,000 VND/kg.<br />

However, there are two problems with defining “high-value” crops by the value per kilogram.<br />

First, many crops which are often considered “high-value” do not actually have unit values that are<br />

greater than rice or maize. For example, fruit <strong>and</strong> vegetables are generally considered “high-value”<br />

agricultural commodities, but the prices for most of the 18 fruit <strong>and</strong> vegetable categories are below<br />

2,000 VND/kg. Second, the value per kilogram is not a good measure of the potential of the crop to<br />

contribute to household income. Yields, labor requirements, growing period, <strong>and</strong> input costs all vary<br />

from crop to crop <strong>and</strong> affect profitability. Even if two crops have the same price, one may be more<br />

profitable to the grower if it has a higher yield, a shorter growing season (allowing more crop cycles<br />

per year), lower labor requirements, or lower input requirements.<br />

13<br />

The sales transactions were recorded over a 12 month period, but they have been adjusted using the<br />

consumer price index to be expressed in January 1998 prices.<br />

Page 61


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Thus, a better indicator of “high-value” crop is the net revenue per hectare or per day of labor.<br />

Since data on labor input is difficult to collect <strong>and</strong> is not available at the crop level from the Vietnam<br />

Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Surveys, we focus on the net revenue per hectare per year. For our purposes, net<br />

revenue is defined as the value of crop production (including sales <strong>and</strong> home consumption) minus the<br />

value of retained seed <strong>and</strong> crops given to laborers as wages-in-kind, the cost of fertilizer <strong>and</strong> other<br />

inputs, spending on hired agricultural labor, <strong>and</strong> the costs of storage <strong>and</strong> marketing 14 .<br />

With regard to non-crop activities, the appropriate measure would be the net revenue per day<br />

of labor or perhaps per unit of investment, but the VLSS data do not provide sufficient detail on labor<br />

<strong>and</strong> capital inputs to carry out this analysis. Thus, we will examine the process of diversification from<br />

crop production to livestock, fisheries, <strong>and</strong> non-farm employment on the premise that these activities<br />

generate higher returns per day of labor. Later in the report, we examine the contribution that these<br />

activities have made in raising rural incomes <strong>and</strong> reducing poverty.<br />

3.7.1 Participation in high-value activities<br />

One measure of the importance of high-value activities among rural households in the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s is the percentage of household that participate in those activities. According to the<br />

2002 VHLSS, virtually all rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s grow crops <strong>and</strong> almost all (97<br />

percent) raise livestock, defined broadly to include not only raising buffalo, cattle, pigs, <strong>and</strong> poultry,<br />

but also activities such as bee keeping, silk worm production, <strong>and</strong> raising snakes <strong>and</strong> frogs. Over onethird<br />

(38 percent) participate in some form of fishery activity, including both aquaculture <strong>and</strong> capture<br />

fisheries. About 84 percent have some forestry income, which includes both agro-forestry <strong>and</strong><br />

harvesting firewood. Thirty two percent earn money from non-farm enterprises, the most common<br />

activities being food processing <strong>and</strong> retail sales. About 44 percent have wage income, <strong>and</strong> threequarters<br />

receive some kind of transfer, either from family members or from government programs<br />

(see Table 3-20).<br />

Looking at changes over time in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, the proportion of households growing<br />

crops <strong>and</strong> raising livestock does not appear to have changed much. Fishery activities were fairly<br />

widespread in the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS, but dropped to 38 percent in the 2002 VHLSS. This pattern<br />

(which reflects a national trend) may indicate a shift from self-provision to relying on purchases from<br />

a smaller number of specialized fishing households 15 .<br />

The proportion of households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s with forestry income appears to have<br />

increased from 27 percent in 1993 to 84 percent in 2002. A similar pattern is observed in most other<br />

regions as well. This expansion may be a reflection of the allocation of upl<strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong>-use certificates,<br />

14<br />

As described in section 3.2, the VLSS questionnaire does not allocate hired labor or storage <strong>and</strong><br />

marketing costs among crops, so it was necessary to allocate these costs in proportion to the value of crop<br />

production within each household.<br />

15<br />

Alternatively, it may be related to a change in the design of the fishery/aquaculture module in the<br />

VHLSS.<br />

Page 62


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

although these figures should be interpreted with caution given differences in the surveys <strong>and</strong> the<br />

difficulties in measuring firewood collection (see Table 3-20).<br />

Table 3-20. Percent of rural households participating in different activities by region<br />

in 1993, 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002<br />

Year <strong>and</strong><br />

Region<br />

Source NU RRD NCC SCC CH SE MRD Total<br />

1993<br />

Crops 98 97 97 90 97 81 84 92<br />

Livestock 97 94 95 85 77 63 79 87<br />

Fisheries 56 57 32 7 3 13 58 43<br />

Forestry 27 13 11 18 7 29 51 25<br />

Enterprise 63 40 38 35 24 48 46 45<br />

Wages 35 44 36 46 48 52 61 46<br />

Transfers 65 65 46 90 77 46 44 59<br />

Other 2 6 4 3 8 6 8 5<br />

1998<br />

Crops 97 98 96 97 98 75 82 92<br />

Livestock 97 95 97 87 85 63 64 86<br />

Fisheries 59 67 51 6 29 21 69 53<br />

Forestry 50 19 54 42 0 35 38 37<br />

Enterprise 40 42 48 29 26 44 40 41<br />

Wages 29 43 43 54 44 58 52 44<br />

Transfers 78 79 87 89 88 86 81 82<br />

Other 4 8 6 3 2 9 4 5<br />

2002<br />

Crops 100 100 100 100 99 99 99 100<br />

Livestock 97 86 94 80 86 64 57 81<br />

Fisheries 38 39 25 10 42 16 64 37<br />

Forestry 84 10 57 52 92 59 71 53<br />

Enterprise 35 40 34 41 33 24 31 35<br />

Wages 45 56 45 59 62 69 59 55<br />

Transfers 75 84 90 73 80 78 78 81<br />

Other 22 19 19 32 27 25 29 24<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 & 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

Similarly, the proportion of rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s with enterprise income<br />

(non-farm self-employment) has fallen from 63 percent in 1993 to 40 percent in 1998 <strong>and</strong> to 35<br />

percent in 2002. This decline is found at the national level as well. Non-farm enterprises may be<br />

undergoing a consolidation, in which enterprises such as retail shops <strong>and</strong> food processors are<br />

becoming fewer in number but larger on average. A alternative hypothesis is that market<br />

liberalization (including import liberalization) <strong>and</strong>/or rising income has led to consumers switching<br />

from locally-made goods to factory-made goods produced in other regions or imported goods. This<br />

could well apply to processed food <strong>and</strong> wood products, though it would not affect retail trade. The<br />

prevalence of wage income in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s does not show a consistent pattern over time, nor<br />

does it at the national level (see Table 3-20).<br />

3.7.2 Participation in high-value crop production<br />

Another type of high-value diversification is the shift toward high-value crops.<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> toward high-value crops usually implies greater commercialization but this is not<br />

always the case. For example, a farmer may shift l<strong>and</strong> from maize for sale to fruit for sale, increasing<br />

household income without necessarily increasing the degree of commercialization. Comparing the<br />

Page 63


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS surveys, there is some evidence of crop diversification among rural households<br />

in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. The proportion of farmers growing rice, sweet potatoes, <strong>and</strong> “other staple<br />

crops” decreased slightly, though they remain the most widespread crops in the region. The<br />

percentage of rural households growing fresh legumes, soybeans, <strong>and</strong> citrus increased. Some crops<br />

Table 3-21. Percent of rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s growing<br />

different crops in 1993, 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002<br />

Year<br />

Crop 1993 1998 2002<br />

Rice 95 94 91<br />

Maize 56 61 64<br />

Sweet potatoes 49 40 30<br />

Potatoes 13 16 6<br />

Cassava 49 51 49<br />

Other staple crops 8 5 5<br />

Kohlrabi, cabbage, cauliflower 53 45 47<br />

Other leafy greens 47 44 67<br />

Tomatoes 12 8 5<br />

Water morning glory 59 54 57<br />

Fresh legumes 20 20 36<br />

Dried legumes 48 30 -<br />

Herbs <strong>and</strong> spices 11 27 -<br />

Other vegetables 42 50 63<br />

Soybeans 28 28 38<br />

Peanuts 41 40 24<br />

Sugar cane 13 17 8<br />

Tobacco 11 7 2<br />

Other annual crops 6 4 5<br />

Tea 20 19 21<br />

Other industrial tree crops 3 2 1<br />

Citrus 12 21 21<br />

Pineapple 10 8 6<br />

Bananas 44 53 46<br />

Mango 5 4 6<br />

Apple 5 9 3<br />

Plum 12 16 10<br />

Papaya 16 21 16<br />

Litchi, longan & rambuttan 12 23 16<br />

Custard apple 7 12 9<br />

Jackfruit, durian 23 25 12<br />

Other fruit trees 6 7 7<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

increased between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998, only to decline between 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002. Examples are litchi <strong>and</strong><br />

longan 16 , sugarcane, <strong>and</strong> custard apple. In the case of litchi <strong>and</strong> longan, the rise <strong>and</strong> fall may be<br />

connected to fluctuations in the access to Chinese markets. In recent years, import controls in China<br />

have been tightened. The proportion growing herbs <strong>and</strong> spices increased sharply between 1993 <strong>and</strong><br />

1998, but this crop category was not included in the 2002 VHLSS (see Table 3-21).<br />

If we group the crops into six categories, the broader trends are easier to see. The proportion<br />

of rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s that grow rice <strong>and</strong> other food has declined, while the<br />

proportion growing fruit <strong>and</strong> annual industrial crops increased over 1993-98 but declined in 1998-<br />

2002. For example, the share of farms growing fruit increased from 62 percent to 78 percent, but then<br />

fell to 67 percent in 2002. This pattern might be explained by the proliferation of fruit promotion<br />

campaigns <strong>and</strong> experimentation by farmers, followed by a consolidation of production in zones with a<br />

16<br />

Although rambuttan is included in this crop category, only longan <strong>and</strong> litchi are grown in the north.<br />

Page 64


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

comparative advantage. The proportion growing vegetables <strong>and</strong> perennial tree crops (mainly tea)<br />

does not show a consistent trend in either direction (see Table 3-22)<br />

Table 3-22.<br />

Percent of rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s growing<br />

each crop category<br />

Year<br />

Crop 1993 1998 2002<br />

Rice 95 94 91<br />

Other food 90 88 84<br />

Vegetables 85 80 92<br />

Fruit 62 78 67<br />

Annual industrial crops 68 73 64<br />

Perennial industrial crops 22 20 24<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

Even without changing the crop mix, farmers may diversify toward high value crops by<br />

reallocating l<strong>and</strong> toward high-value crops. For this reason, it is useful to look at the share of<br />

agricultural l<strong>and</strong> planted with different crops as shown in Table 3-23. These figures refer to sown<br />

area, so that, for example, the area under double cropped rice is counted twice.<br />

Table 3-23. Percent of crop area allocated to each crop in the rural Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s in 1993, 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002<br />

Year<br />

Crop 1993 1998 2002<br />

Rice 53.2 49.0 44.3<br />

Maize 16.8 12.6 25.7<br />

Sweet potatoes 3.1 2.0 1.6<br />

Potatoes 0.2 0.4 0.3<br />

Cassava 6.4 6.4 8.8<br />

Other staple crops 0.2 0.3 0.0<br />

Kohlrabi, cabbage, cauliflower 0.8 0.8 0.8<br />

Other leafy greens 0.5 0.5 0.9<br />

Tomatoes 0.3 0.2 0.1<br />

Water morning glory 0.4 0.3 0.4<br />

Fresh legumes 0.1 0.1 0.5<br />

Other vegetables 0.5 0.9 0.0<br />

Soybeans 2.2 3.6 2.3<br />

Peanuts 2.4 2.3 1.2<br />

Sugar cane 2.1 5.9 1.2<br />

Tobacco 1.2 0.7 0.1<br />

Other annual crops 1.0 1.3 0.4<br />

Tea 1.0 0.9 7.1<br />

Other industrial tree crops 0.1 0.7 0.0<br />

Cashew 0.0 0.0 0.0<br />

Citrus 0.3 0.7 0.2<br />

Pineapple 0.2 0.2 0.1<br />

Bananas 0.7 1.1 1.0<br />

Mango 0.1 0.4 0.0<br />

Apple 0.4 0.1 0.0<br />

Plum 0.3 0.3 0.1<br />

Papaya 0.0 0.0 0.1<br />

Litchi, longan & rambuttan 1.0 1.9 2.5<br />

Custard apple 0.2 0.4 0.1<br />

Jackfruit, durian 3.3 4.4 0.1<br />

Other fruit trees 1.0 1.6 0.0<br />

Total 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

Even in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, where rice plays a less dominant role than in the lowl<strong>and</strong>s, rice<br />

accounts for almost half the sown crop area. This percentage has declined from 53 percent in 1993 to<br />

49 percent in 1998 <strong>and</strong> to 44 percent in 2002. These results are consistent with the official<br />

Page 65


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

agricultural statistics from GSO reported in Table 2-4 in which the share of agricultural l<strong>and</strong> allocated<br />

to rice fell from 50 percent in 1995 to 44 percent in 2002.<br />

According to Table 3-23, the proportion of sown area allocated to maize doubled from 12.6<br />

percent in 1998 to 25.7 percent in 2002. This increase may be somewhat exaggerated, but the rapid<br />

growth in maize production in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> is well documented in agricultural statistics.<br />

According to Table 2-5, maize output in the region grew 86 percent (13 percent annually) between<br />

1995 <strong>and</strong> 2000. According to the MARD (2002), maize area in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> represented 22<br />

percent of agricultural l<strong>and</strong> in 2000.<br />

According to the surveys, the area allocated to sweet potato has declined from 3.1 percent in<br />

1993 to 1.6 percent in 2002. The share of crop l<strong>and</strong> planted with tea <strong>and</strong> litchi/longan has increased,<br />

while the share allocated to citrus, sugarcane, soybeans, <strong>and</strong> peanuts increased over 1993-98 <strong>and</strong> then<br />

decreased over 1998-2002. Although data are not available for 2002, agricultural statistics from GSO<br />

show increases in area planted to citrus, sugarcane, peanuts, <strong>and</strong> soybeans over 1996-2000. This<br />

discrepancy may be related to design differences between the 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

Examining the share of the sown area allocated to the six crop categories, it is clear that<br />

farmers in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s have shifted cropl<strong>and</strong> away from rice but the surveys are not<br />

consistent in telling us which crops have gained. According to the 1998 VLSS, the shift has been<br />

mainly to fruit <strong>and</strong> annual industrial crops, while the 2002 VHLSS indicates that the expansion has<br />

been in maize <strong>and</strong> tea (see Table 3-24).<br />

Table 3-24. Percent of crop area allocated to each crop category in the rural<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s in 1993, 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002<br />

Year<br />

Crop 1993 1998 2002<br />

Rice 53.2 49.0 44.4<br />

Other food 26.7 21.6 36.4<br />

Vegetables 2.6 2.7 2.7<br />

Fruit 7.5 11.1 4.2<br />

Annual industrial 9.0 13.9 5.2<br />

Perennial industrial 1.1 1.6 7.1<br />

Total 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

3.8 Contribution of diversification to rural income growth<br />

This section measures the contribution of different components of income to overall growth in<br />

rural income. First, we examine the contribution of diversification from crop production into highervalue<br />

activities such as livestock, fisheries, non-farm enterprises, <strong>and</strong> wage income. The contribution<br />

of a given activity is calculated as the change in income from that source as a percentage of the<br />

overall change in income. Second, we explore the contribution of crop diversification to the growth<br />

in overall net revenue from crop production. In this case, diversification is measured as the increase<br />

in income that can be attributed to the reallocation of l<strong>and</strong> among crops, holding constant yields,<br />

prices, <strong>and</strong> total area cropped. The method is described in more detail in Section 3.2.4.<br />

Page 66


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

3.8.1 Contribution of income diversification<br />

<strong>Income</strong> diversification in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Among rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, net income increased from 6.9 million<br />

VND per household per year in 1993 to 11.0 million VND in 1998 <strong>and</strong> to 12.9 million VND in 2002<br />

(expressed in constant terms at January 2002 prices). These imply growth rates of 59 percent over<br />

1993-1998 <strong>and</strong> 17 percent over 1998-2002 17 . The composition of income has changed slowly over<br />

time, with agriculture <strong>and</strong> enterprise income becoming less important <strong>and</strong> wage <strong>and</strong> forestry income<br />

becoming more important. <strong>Income</strong> from livestock, fisheries, <strong>and</strong> transfers remained roughly constant<br />

as a proportion of the total. Although the importance of crop income has declined, crop <strong>and</strong> livestock<br />

income still represent over half of the rural income in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s (see Table 3-25 <strong>and</strong><br />

Figure 3-2).<br />

Table 3-25. Contribution of each source of income to overall income in the rural<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Source Net income Share of income_ ___<br />

1993 1998 2002 1993 1998 2002<br />

Crops 3,249 5,065 4,939 47 46 38<br />

Livestock 785 1,097 1,657 11 10 13<br />

Fisheries 214 310 256 3 3 2<br />

Forestry 137 380 986 2 3 8<br />

Enterprise 1,309 1,941 1,324 19 18 10<br />

Wages 539 982 2,009 8 9 16<br />

Transfers 680 1,146 1,507 10 10 12<br />

Other 14 64 229 0 1 2<br />

Total 6,928 10,985 12,907 100 100 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

Figure 3-2. Contribution of different factors to crop income growth by year<br />

100%<br />

Share of income (%)<br />

90%<br />

80%<br />

70%<br />

60%<br />

50%<br />

40%<br />

30%<br />

20%<br />

10%<br />

47% 46%<br />

38%<br />

Other<br />

Transfers<br />

Wages<br />

Enterprise<br />

Forestry<br />

Fisheries<br />

Livestock<br />

Crops<br />

0%<br />

1993 1998 2002<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

17<br />

These growth rates differ somewhat from the per capita income growth rates reported in Table 3-4<br />

because of changes in the average household size.<br />

Page 67


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Table 3-26 shows the growth rates for income from each source <strong>and</strong> the contribution of each<br />

type of income to overall income growth. For example, between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 crop income rose<br />

from 3.2 million VND to 5.1 million VND in 1998, while total income rose from 6.9 million VND to<br />

11.0 million VND. Thus, the increase in net income from crop production (1.9 million VND)<br />

contributed 45 percent of the increase in total net revenue (4.0 million VND) over this period 18 .<br />

Applying similar calculations to other activities, it appears that the growth in enterprise<br />

income accounts for 16 percent of the overall growth. This is somewhat surprising in light of the<br />

results presented in Section 3.5.1 showing that the proportion of households with enterprise income<br />

fell substantially between the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS surveys. Given that the proportion of rural<br />

households in the region with enterprise income has fallen but the total enterprise income increased 48<br />

percent in real terms, the data suggest that the small enterprise sector is undergoing some form of<br />

consolidation, as hypothesized in Section 3.5.1. In other words, fewer household operate enterprises<br />

but the average size of the enterprises is rising.<br />

Table 3-26.<br />

Growth of income from each source <strong>and</strong> contribution to overall growth<br />

of each source in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Source<br />

Contribution<br />

Growth<br />

to overall growth<br />

1993-98 1998-02 1993-98 1998-02<br />

Crops 56 -2 45 -7<br />

Livestock 40 51 8 29<br />

Fisheries 45 -17 2 -3<br />

Forestry 178 159 6 32<br />

Enterprise 48 -32 16 -32<br />

Wages 82 104 11 53<br />

Transfers 69 32 11 19<br />

Other 344 258 1 9<br />

Total 59 17 100 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS.<br />

The growth in wage income <strong>and</strong> in transfers each account for 11 percent of the overall growth<br />

in the net revenue of rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s over 1993-98, while growth in<br />

livestock income accounts for 8 percent of the total growth. Although forestry income shows the<br />

fastest growth among the eight income sources, its contribution to overall growth is still relatively<br />

small (6 percent) because it is such a small source of income (see Table 3-26).<br />

If we define livestock, fisheries, <strong>and</strong> forestry as high-value agricultural activities, then the<br />

growth in high-value agricultural activities accounts for 16 percent of the growth in overall income. If<br />

we consider non-farm enterprises <strong>and</strong> wage labor together, then growth in non-farm activities<br />

represents 27 percent of the overall growth in income.<br />

The contribution of each type of income to income growth over 1998-2002 shows a very<br />

erratic pattern. According to Table 3-26, growth in wage income <strong>and</strong> forestry account for 85 percent<br />

of the overall income growth, while income from enterprises, crop production, <strong>and</strong> fisheries fell over<br />

18<br />

If we carry out the same analysis but limit the sample to those households in both the 1993 <strong>and</strong><br />

1998 samples, the results are almost identical. For example, crop income growth accounts for 46 percent of the<br />

rural income growth <strong>and</strong> growth in enterprise income contributes 16 percent over the period 1993-98.<br />

Page 68


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

this period. These results are very different from the 1993-98 results, <strong>and</strong> they are difficult to<br />

reconcile with economic trends in Vietnam. One explanation is that, because the overall growth rate<br />

is modest, the margin of error for the ratio of sector growth to overall growth has a large margin of<br />

error. In addition, differences in the way the VHLSS collected income data <strong>and</strong>/or differences in the<br />

sampling design may have contributed to these. Because the patterns by region <strong>and</strong> by income<br />

category are even more unpredictable, we focus on the 1993-98 results in the next section.<br />

<strong>Income</strong> diversification in other regions<br />

How does the contribution of each income source to overall growth in rural income vary<br />

across regions Over the period 1993-98, the contribution of crop production to income growth<br />

varied from 30 percent in the North Central Coast <strong>and</strong> the Southeast to 75 percent in the Central<br />

Highl<strong>and</strong>s. The small contribution in the Southeast is due to the high level of urbanization <strong>and</strong> the<br />

availability of non-farm employment which mean that wages are an important source of income<br />

growth in this region. The large contribution of crop income in the Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s is linked to the<br />

boom in coffee production during the mid-1990s. In the other three regions, crop production accounts<br />

for 47-58 percent of the overall growth (see Table 3-27) 19 .<br />

In spite of the variation in the contribution of crop production growth to overall growth, it is<br />

noteworthy that crop production is the most important source of rural income growth in all seven<br />

regions of Vietnam. The second largest contributor to rural income growth varies across regions. In<br />

the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, the Red River Delta, the Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> the Mekong River Delta, nonfarm<br />

enterprise income is the second largest contributor to rural income growth. In the South Central<br />

Coast <strong>and</strong> the Southeast, wages are the second largest contributor (see Table 3-27). In contrast, for<br />

urban households (not shown in the table), the sources of income growth are split almost exactly<br />

between wages, 50 percent, <strong>and</strong> non-farm enterprise income, 49 percent.<br />

Table 3-27. Contribution to overall growth of each income source in rural areas by region<br />

between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998<br />

Source N. Red N.C. S.C. C. South- Mekong<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s River Coast Coast High- east River Rural<br />

Delta l<strong>and</strong>s Delta average<br />

---------(percent of overall income growth)---------<br />

Crops 45 47 30 55 75 30 58 48<br />

Livestock 8 -1 7 8 10 10 9 7<br />

Fisheries 2 4 3 0 1 1 8 3<br />

Forestry 6 0 5 2 0 2 -2 2<br />

Enterprise 16 21 7 2 11 10 12 11<br />

Wages 11 16 17 30 1 26 7 15<br />

Transfers 11 12 28 3 1 18 11 13<br />

Other 1 1 3 -1 1 3 -3 1<br />

Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS.<br />

19<br />

If we carry out this analysis only on households that are in both the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS samples,<br />

the results are quite similar.<br />

Page 69


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

<strong>Income</strong> diversification by income group<br />

This section compares rice <strong>and</strong> poor households in terms of the income growth over 1993-98<br />

<strong>and</strong> the contribution of each income source to overall growth over this period. There are two ways to<br />

define the income categories. The top half of Table 3-28 divides households according to the national<br />

quintile of per capita expenditure for that year. In other words, it compares the poorest 20 percent in<br />

1993 with the poorest 20 percent in 1998. The average income in the poorest quintile rose 46 percent<br />

while the average income in the richest quintile rose 125 percent. This implies that the gap between<br />

the poor <strong>and</strong> rich has widened, even though the poor have benefited from solid income growth.<br />

The bottom half of Table 3-28 makes use of the fact that the 1998 VLSS contains many of the<br />

same households that were in the 1993 VLSS. In this section, we limit our analysis to households that<br />

were in both surveys, of which there are 4,299 in total <strong>and</strong> 635 in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. By<br />

doing this, we can classify households according to their st<strong>and</strong>ard of living in the base year 1993,<br />

regardless of how much their incomes changed over the period 1993-98. More specifically, the<br />

sample is divided into quintiles according to the value of per capita expenditure in 1993. When the<br />

households are organized in this way, the growth in net income over 1993-98 does not show any<br />

consistent pattern across expenditure quintiles. The growth in net income among the poorest quintile<br />

was 57 percent, compared to 46 percent in the highest quintile. The paradoxical result is that the gap<br />

between the poor <strong>and</strong> the rich in the rural areas of Vietnam has widened, but those who were poor in<br />

1993 gained as much as those who were rich in 1993, on average.<br />

Table 3-28. <strong>Income</strong> growth between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 by expenditure category<br />

Expenditure<br />

category in Net <strong>Income</strong> Growth<br />

each year 1993 1998 1993-98<br />

---(1000 VND/hh/year)--- (percent)<br />

Poorest 4,715 6,883 46<br />

2 6,238 11,219 80<br />

3 8,691 12,128 40<br />

4 8,765 16,606 89<br />

Richest 11,385 25,624 125<br />

Expenditure<br />

category in Net <strong>Income</strong> Growth<br />

1993 1993 1998 1993-98<br />

---(1000 VND/hh/year)--- (percent)<br />

Poorest 4,823 7,557 57<br />

2 6,296 9,520 51<br />

3 8,808 13,836 57<br />

4 9,113 14,818 63<br />

Richest 11,385 16,656 46<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS. Top half of the table includes all households. Bottom half<br />

includes only households in both 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 samples.<br />

The contribution of each income source to overall income <strong>and</strong> to income growth for each<br />

income group is shown in Table 3-29 <strong>and</strong> Figure 3-3. Here, the quintiles are defined in each year<br />

(1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998), as in the top half of the previous table 20 . The top half of the table shows that crop<br />

20 Although not shown here, the results are very similar if the income categories are defined in terms of<br />

the 1993 quintile, using only households interviewed in both years. In this case, the contribution of crop<br />

Page 70


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

<strong>and</strong> forestry income are more important to poor households, while enterprise income <strong>and</strong> transfers are<br />

more important to richer households. For example, the contribution of crop income declines from 59<br />

percent in the poorest group to 22 percent in the richest.<br />

The bottom half of Table 3-29 shows that growth in crop production is the most important<br />

source of income growth for poor households, accounting for over two-thirds of the total. The<br />

contribution of crop production to income growth declines from 69 percent among households in the<br />

poorest group to just 14 percent among those in the richest group. In contrast, the contribution of<br />

non-farm enterprise income to rural income growth is greatest among higher income households.<br />

Among the poorest households, enterprise income actually declined, so its “contribution” was –12<br />

percent. In the middle three quintiles, the contribution of enterprise income ranged from -13 to 34<br />

percent. In the highest income category, growth in non-farm enterprise income accounted for almost<br />

half of the overall income growth. Livestock <strong>and</strong> forestry income make a greater contribution to the<br />

income growth of poor households than rich, while the contribution of wage income seems to be<br />

greatest in the middle income categories.<br />

If we limit the analysis to households in both the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 samples <strong>and</strong> define the<br />

categories according to the per capita expenditure in 1993 (rather than 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 respectively),<br />

the results are similar. The contribution of crop income growth falls from 65 percent in the poorest<br />

category to 33 percent in the richest category.<br />

Table 3-29. Contribution of each income source to income <strong>and</strong> income growth<br />

by expenditure category in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, 1993-1998<br />

<strong>Income</strong> Poorest 2 3 4 Richest Average<br />

source<br />

---------(percent of income in 1998)--------<br />

Crops 59 53 50 31 22 38<br />

Livestock 12 9 10 9 8 13<br />

Fisheries 3 3 3 2 2 2<br />

Forestry 5 4 4 2 1 8<br />

Enterprise 9 14 12 30 33 10<br />

Wages 6 10 11 13 6 16<br />

Transfers 6 6 10 13 24 12<br />

Other 0 0 1 0 3 2<br />

Total 100 100 100 100 100 100<br />

-------(percent of income growth 93-98)-----<br />

Crops 69 55 63 23 14 45<br />

Livestock 15 7 3 7 7 8<br />

Fisheries 2 2 4 4 1 2<br />

Forestry 12 6 7 2 2 6<br />

Enterprise -12 14 -13 34 49 16<br />

Wages 5 14 20 15 3 11<br />

Transfers 10 3 14 16 19 11<br />

Other 0 0 2 0 5 1<br />

Total 100 100 100 100 100 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS<br />

income growth falls from 65 percent among the poorest income group to 33 percent among the richest income<br />

group. The contribution of enterprise income growth rises from –17 percent in the poorest category to 58<br />

percent in the richest category.<br />

Page 71


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Figure 3-3. Contribution of different sources to rural income growth, 1993-98<br />

120<br />

% of income growth<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

Other<br />

Transfers<br />

Wages<br />

Enterprise<br />

Forestry<br />

Fisheries<br />

Livestock<br />

Crops<br />

-20<br />

Poorest 2 3 4 Richest<br />

Expenditure category<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS.<br />

Note: Some columns extend below zero because households in that group have average enterprise income below zero<br />

(losses). The other sources must add up to over 100 percent to offset these negative figures.<br />

<strong>Income</strong> diversification by sex of the head of household<br />

Are the sources of income growth different between male- <strong>and</strong> female-headed households in<br />

the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s As discussed earlier, female-headed households have per capita income<br />

levels equal to or slightly above those of male-headed households, on average, <strong>and</strong> the growth in<br />

income appears to be similar for both groups. Table 3-32 shows the contribution of each source to<br />

overall income growth for male- <strong>and</strong> female-headed households. Almost half (46 percent) of the<br />

income growth of male-headed households can be attributed to growth in crop production, compared<br />

to just 33 percent among female-headed households. The other difference between them is that<br />

transfer income has grown more for female-headed households, contributing 40 percent of total<br />

income growth. These transfers are mainly remittances from family members (who may include a<br />

husb<strong>and</strong>) working elsewhere. By contrast, for male-headed households, growth in transfers represents<br />

just 7 percent of the total.<br />

Page 72


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Table 3-30. Contribution to overall income growth of each income source<br />

by gender of head of household in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s,<br />

1993-1998<br />

<strong>Income</strong><br />

Head of household<br />

source Male Female Average<br />

(percent of overall income growth)<br />

Crops 46 33 45<br />

Livestock 8 4 8<br />

Fisheries 1 9 2<br />

Forestry 6 5 6<br />

Enterprise 19 -10 16<br />

Wages 11 12 11<br />

Transfers 7 40 11<br />

Other 0 8 1<br />

Total 100 100 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS<br />

<strong>Income</strong> diversification by ethnicity of the head of household<br />

Have income growth patterns differed between Kinh/Hoa households <strong>and</strong> ethnic minority<br />

households in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s Earlier in this chapter, we showed that ethnic minority<br />

households tend to be poorer than average <strong>and</strong> that the growth in their income has also been below<br />

average. Here, we compare the composition of the income growth between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998. Growth<br />

in crop income accounts for three-quarters of the income growth of ethnic minority households.<br />

Forestry <strong>and</strong> wages are also important, each contributing 10-12 percent of the total. Enterprise<br />

income has declined, resulting in a negative contribution (see Table 3-31 <strong>and</strong> Figure 3-4).<br />

In contrast, crop income barely contributed one-quarter of the total income growth for<br />

Kinh/Hoa households. The largest contributor to income growth was enterprise income, which<br />

accounted for over one-third (34 percent) of the total. Forestry is much less important as a source of<br />

income growth for these households compared to ethnic minority households.<br />

Table 3-31. Contribution to overall income growth of each income source<br />

by ethnicity in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, 1993-1998<br />

<strong>Income</strong><br />

Ethnicity of head of household<br />

source Kinh/Hoa Minority Average<br />

(percent of overall income growth)<br />

Crops 26 74 45<br />

Livestock 8 7 8<br />

Fisheries 2 3 2<br />

Forestry 2 12 6<br />

Enterprise 34 -13 16<br />

Wages 12 10 11<br />

Transfers 14 7 11<br />

Other 2 0 1<br />

Total 100 100 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS<br />

Page 73


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Figure 3-4. Contribution of different factors to rural income growth by ethnicity, 1993-98<br />

120<br />

% of income growth<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

Other<br />

Transfers<br />

Wages<br />

Enterprise<br />

Forestry<br />

Fisheries<br />

Livestock<br />

Crops<br />

0<br />

-20<br />

Kinh<br />

Minority<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS<br />

Note: The ethnic minority column extends below zero because households in that group have average enterprise<br />

income below zero (losses). The other sources must add up to over 100 percent to offset these negative figures.<br />

3.8.2 Contribution of crop diversification<br />

The previous section compared the contribution of crop production <strong>and</strong> other economic<br />

activities to overall rural income growth. This section focuses on the composition of the growth in<br />

crop income. Because the design of the 2002 VHLSS does not allow the calculation of net income<br />

from each crop, this analysis focuses on the comparison of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS.<br />

Crop diversification in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

According to the Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Surveys, the net revenue from crop production<br />

among rural farmers in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s increased by about 2.0 million VND/farm/year in real<br />

terms between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998. 21 This section shows the composition of this growth by crop <strong>and</strong> by<br />

source of growth: area expansion, higher prices, yield improvement, <strong>and</strong> diversification into highervalue<br />

crops. The calculations for this analysis are explained in Section 3.2.4.<br />

The last column in Table 3-32 shows the growth in net income from different crops between<br />

the two VLSS surveys. The growth in net income from rice was 618 thous<strong>and</strong> VND per household<br />

21<br />

The income figures in this section differ somewhat from the ones presented in Table 3-25 for two<br />

reasons. First, the sample for this analysis is smaller, being restricted to rural households in the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s who grow crops rather than all rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. Second, crop production was<br />

defined earlier to include by-products such as straw, hay, stems, <strong>and</strong> leaves. Since these by-products are not<br />

linked to specific crops in the questionnaire, they were excluded from this analysis.<br />

Page 74


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

per year, about 29 percent of the overall increase in net income from crops. Sugarcane <strong>and</strong><br />

litchi/longan each contributed another 18-19 percent of the overall increase in net income from crop<br />

production. No other crop represents more than 6 percent of the total growth in crop income.<br />

The other way to disaggregate the growth in crop income is by the source of the growth:<br />

overall area increase, increased prices, higher yields, <strong>and</strong> diversification toward higher-value crops.<br />

This decomposition is shown in each row of Table 3-32. For example, yield increases explain more<br />

than three-quarters of the VND 618 thous<strong>and</strong> increase in the net income from rice production.<br />

Similarly, yield growth is the main factor behind the expansion in maize output.<br />

Price increases did not contribute much to the growth in the value of rice production, but it<br />

did explain much of the growth in value of sweet potatoes, cassava, <strong>and</strong> sugar cane. In the case of<br />

sugar cane, the higher prices are due to the government policy to achieve sugar self-sufficiency by<br />

restricting imports, which has raised the domestic price of sugar (<strong>and</strong> indirectly sugarcane) far above<br />

the international price.<br />

Table 3-32. Composition of growth in crop income in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, 1993-1998<br />

Crop Area Price Higher Crop diver- Total<br />

Expansion Increases yields sification change<br />

Rice 193 22 489 -104 618<br />

Maize 30 38 111 -60 105<br />

Sweet potatoes 7 126 -5 -20 66<br />

Potatoes 1 10 -2 6 18<br />

Cassava 20 112 -12 1 126<br />

Other staple crops 1 -2 2 5 6<br />

Kohlrabi, cabbage, caulif. 6 51 3 -4 60<br />

Other leafy greens 3 21 -3 1 24<br />

Tomatoes 2 32 -3 -7 13<br />

Water morning glory 6 47 26 -9 86<br />

Fresh legumes 1 3 0 -1 3<br />

Other vegetables 4 9 -6 24 35<br />

Soybeans 9 -11 10 49 59<br />

Peanuts 11 -30 54 -2 16<br />

Sugar cane 11 141 -26 161 421<br />

Tobacco 6 20 18 -21 12<br />

Other annual crops 0 -1 11 0 0<br />

Tea 5 -17 54 -4 17<br />

Other industrial tree crops 0 -1 -1 11 -1<br />

Cashew 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Citrus 1 0 0 9 12<br />

Pineapple 1 0 -2 2 -1<br />

Bananas 5 -5 3 27 31<br />

Mango 1 -2 -4 8 -4<br />

Apple 0 -1 42 -3 3<br />

Plum 1 7 2 1 15<br />

Papaya 1 2 10 -2 10<br />

Litchi, longan & rambuttan 4 22 89 31 384<br />

Custard apple 1 0 2 7 14<br />

Jackfruit, durian 2 8 -7 6 6<br />

Other fruit trees 1 1 -2 5 3<br />

Total 333 602 852 121 2,157<br />

Row percentage 15% 28% 40% 6% 100%<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLS<br />

Note: See Section 2.4 <strong>and</strong> accompanying text for explanation. Columns may not add up to total because interaction<br />

term is not shown.<br />

The diversification column gives the increase in the value of crop income due to reallocation<br />

of l<strong>and</strong> away from or toward that crop, holding prices, yields, <strong>and</strong> total cropped area constant.<br />

Page 75


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Expansion of sugarcane, litchi/longan, <strong>and</strong> “other industrial tree crops” all represented an increase in<br />

crop income due to crop diversification.<br />

The bottom two rows of Table 3-32 show the decomposition of crop income growth by<br />

source, summing across all crops. The largest factor in the growth of crop income in the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s was yield increases, which accounted for 852 VND/farm/year in additional income or 40<br />

percent of the total increase in crop income. In fact, yield increases in rice alone account for almost<br />

one quarter (23 percent) of the overall increase in crop income. Price increases represented about 28<br />

percent of the crop income growth, while expansion in cropped area accounts for 15 percent of the<br />

total. According to the comparison of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS studies, crop diversification increased<br />

the average annual net revenue from crop production in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s by VND 121<br />

thous<strong>and</strong>/farm. In other words, if farmers in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s had maintained the same total crop<br />

area, the same yields, <strong>and</strong> the same real price, but had reallocated their l<strong>and</strong> among crops following<br />

the historical pattern between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998, their crop income would have increased VND 121<br />

thous<strong>and</strong>/farm. This represents about 6 percent of the total increase in income from crop production<br />

between the two surveys (see Figure 3-5).<br />

Figure 3-5. Contribution of different factors to crop income growth<br />

in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, 1993-98<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong><br />

6%<br />

Interaction<br />

6%<br />

Area<br />

15%<br />

Price<br />

28%<br />

Yield<br />

40%<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS.<br />

If we limit the analysis to households in both the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSS samples, the results<br />

are somewhat different. Yield growth accounts for 50 percent of the overall growth in rural income,<br />

while price increases account for 34 percent, crop diversification 9 percent, <strong>and</strong> area expansion just 3<br />

percent. Overall, these results indicate that, while crop diversification has contributed to income<br />

Page 76


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

growth in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, it has not been as important as growth in yields <strong>and</strong> increases in<br />

real prices.<br />

Crop diversification in other regions<br />

The same analysis can be carried out for the rural areas of the other regions. In the interest of<br />

saving space, we do not present the crop-level results, but Table 3-33 summarizes the contribution of<br />

each factor in crop income growth for the rural areas of each region. Area expansion plays a modest<br />

role in crop income growth in the Red River Delta <strong>and</strong> the two central coast regions. In fact, the Red<br />

Table 3-33. Sources of growth in net income from crop production by region, 1993-1998<br />

Crop<br />

Areas Price Higher diversi-<br />

Region expansion increase yield fication Interaction Total<br />

N Upl<strong>and</strong>s 15 28 40 6 11 100<br />

Red R Delta -16 78 44 10 -16 100<br />

NC Coast -1 60 29 12 0 100<br />

SC Coast 10 52 23 2 13 100<br />

C Highl<strong>and</strong>s 4 31 46 25 -6 100<br />

Southeast 73 22 -9 26 -12 100<br />

Mekong Delta 28 21 23 17 11 100<br />

Average 15 42 29 12 2 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSSs.<br />

River Delta shows a negative contribution, implying that the area cropped per farm household<br />

declined slightly between the two surveys. This is not surprising given that the growth of Hanoi <strong>and</strong><br />

the high value of l<strong>and</strong> are leading to the conversion of agricultural l<strong>and</strong> to residential, industrial, <strong>and</strong><br />

commercial uses. In contrast, area expansion is the most important growth factor in the Southeast.<br />

Although the growth of Ho Chi Minh City is also leading to conversion of farml<strong>and</strong>, the sown area<br />

per farm household has still increased. Increased cropping intensity probably accounts for much of<br />

this growth in sown area.<br />

On a national level, crop diversification accounted for 12 percent of the growth in crop<br />

income between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998. The contribution of crop diversification to crop income growth is<br />

highest in the Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> Southeast. In the Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s, this reflects the expansion<br />

of coffee production in the mid-1990s. In the Southeast, farmers are reallocating l<strong>and</strong> from rice to the<br />

cultivation of fruit <strong>and</strong> other higher-value commercial crops for export <strong>and</strong> sale to Ho Chi Minh City.<br />

At the national level, yield increases represented 29 percent of the growth, <strong>and</strong> higher real prices<br />

contributed 42 percent 22 .<br />

Crop diversification by income group<br />

The growth rate in crop income does not vary in a consistent way with the level of per capita<br />

expenditure in 1993. In other words, poor households in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s experienced as<br />

22<br />

If we focus the analysis on households in both the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 survey, the results are very<br />

similar. Price increases account for 45 percent of the crop income growth, higher yields 29 percent, crop<br />

diversification 14 percent, <strong>and</strong> area expansion 11 percent.<br />

Page 77


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

much growth in crop production income as higher income households in that region. The<br />

composition of this growth does, however, vary across income groups. Among the poorest quintile of<br />

farmers, the increase in yields accounts for about 60 percent of the increase in crop income (see Table<br />

3-34).<br />

The contributions of area expansion, yield increases, higher prices, <strong>and</strong> crop diversification to<br />

crop income growth in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s shows a somewhat erratic pattern. Area expansion<br />

seems to have played a more important role in crop income growth among the households that had<br />

relatively high income. This result suggests that households with relatively high incomes in 1993<br />

were able to use those resources to secure more l<strong>and</strong> for planting crops, either through the l<strong>and</strong><br />

allocation process, through the (formal or informal) purchase of l<strong>and</strong>-use certificates, or through l<strong>and</strong><br />

rental. The contribution of yield increases, though inconsistent, seems to indicate that this factor<br />

plays a more important role in the crop income growth of poor rural households. This result is<br />

plausible since yields can be increased by applying labor more intensively <strong>and</strong> through the use of<br />

improved seed <strong>and</strong> fertilizer, which are generally scale-neutral forms of agricultural technology 23 .<br />

Though the pattern is not consistent, crop diversification may play a somewhat greater role in the crop<br />

income growth of higher income rural households. This result is supported by findings from the<br />

Qualitative Social Assessment, in which higher income farmers were more likely to cite crop<br />

diversification as an explanation for increases in their income over time (see Chapter 5).<br />

Table 3-34. Sources of growth in net income from crop production by expenditure category<br />

Crop<br />

Expenditure Areas Price Higher diversicategory<br />

expansion increase yield fication Interaction Total<br />

Poorest -5 30 61 10 4 100<br />

2 12 33 48 0 9 100<br />

3 -18 57 68 9 -16 100<br />

4 24 32 40 3 1 100<br />

Richest 68 32 -3 27 -24 100<br />

Average 16 37 43 10 -6 100<br />

Source: Analysis of the 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 VLSSs (panel households only).<br />

Note: Expenditure categories are defined according to the level in 1993.<br />

These patterns are also seen across quintiles in other regions. Combining all the rural farm<br />

households together <strong>and</strong> classifying them by expenditure quintile, we see that crop diversification <strong>and</strong><br />

area expansion contribute more to crop income growth among higher income households than among<br />

poor households. Furthermore, as in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, poor households rely more on yield<br />

increases to boost the value of their crop income.<br />

23<br />

Because seed <strong>and</strong> fertilizer can be purchased in small quantities, this type of agricultural technology<br />

is considered more scale-neutral (benefiting small <strong>and</strong> large farmers equally) than mechanical technology.<br />

Page 78


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

3.9 Determinants of income diversification<br />

This section examines the effect of different household characteristics on patterns of income<br />

diversification among rural households in Vietnam using data from the 1998 Vietnam Living<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey. The hypothesis is that the share of income from different sources is influenced by<br />

the characteristics of the household, particularly the amount <strong>and</strong> quality of labor, the amount <strong>and</strong><br />

quality of l<strong>and</strong>, access to markets, access to electricity, <strong>and</strong> the region. We use a linear model in<br />

which the income share is a function of household characteristics 24 . The characteristics included in<br />

the analysis are 25 :<br />

• age of the head of household (years),<br />

• age squared of the head,<br />

• education of the head of household (years),<br />

• household head is a member of ethnic minority (=0 if Kinh or Hoa, =1 otherwise),<br />

• household size (members),<br />

• proportion of household members under 10 (fraction),<br />

• proportion of household members over 60 (fraction),<br />

• female-headed household (=1 if female-headed),<br />

• household has electricity in the home,<br />

• annual crop l<strong>and</strong> (m2),<br />

• perennial crop l<strong>and</strong> (m2),<br />

• irrigated crop l<strong>and</strong> (m2),<br />

• distance from village to a paved road (km),<br />

• number of months per year road to village is impassible, <strong>and</strong><br />

• dummy variables for region (Red River Delta is reference region).<br />

Access to credit, defined as the ability to obtain a loan, would be a useful variable to include,<br />

but the VLSS can only tell us whether or not a household has actually received credit. This variable is<br />

less useful in the regression analysis because it is endogenous. A farmer may seek a loan because he<br />

wants to diversify, so that the coefficient would be affected by simultaneity bias.<br />

The first model estimates the share of income from crop production (see Table 3-35). Crop<br />

production is represents a smaller share of net income when the head of household has more<br />

education, presumably because education opens up opportunities for wage <strong>and</strong> enterprise income.<br />

Crop income is also a smaller share of the total when the head is female, probably due to the more<br />

limited availability of family labor <strong>and</strong> the greater likelihood of remittance income (as discussed<br />

below). Not surprisingly, the crop income share is also positively associated with the amount of<br />

24<br />

Because income shares are “clumped” at zero <strong>and</strong> (to a lesser degree) one, the assumption of a<br />

normally distributed error term is violated in this situation. The usual method of dealing with this situation<br />

would be to use a censored regression model (similar to a Tobit) with censoring below 0 <strong>and</strong> above 1.<br />

Unfortunately, the presence of negative values for net income (particularly for livestock income <strong>and</strong> enterprise<br />

income) means that the income share may be less than zero or greater than one, so that the assumptions of the<br />

Tobit model are also violated. Both linear <strong>and</strong> Tobit models were estimated <strong>and</strong> the results are broadly<br />

consistent, so we present on the results of the linear model.<br />

25<br />

Some variables were not used in the analysis because they might be endogenous (influenced by the<br />

occupation decision). For example, “credit” was not included because the choice of occupation could influence<br />

the decision whether to apply for credit. The VLSS did not collect information on the availability of credit.<br />

Page 79


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

annual crop l<strong>and</strong>, the amount of perennial crop l<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the amount of irrigated crop l<strong>and</strong>. Holding<br />

other factors constant, the share of income from crop production in rural households in the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s is similar to that of rural households in the Red River Delta, but greater than the share in<br />

most other regions. The regional differences are quite large: other things being equal, the share of<br />

crop income is over 30 percentage points lower in the Southeast than in the Red River Delta <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. It is interesting to note that ethnicity <strong>and</strong> distance from a paved road are not<br />

related to the share of income from crop production.<br />

Table 3-35. Linear regression model of shares of income from<br />

crop production<br />

Dependent variable: Share of income of crop production<br />

Number of obs = 4243<br />

F( 20, 4222) = 23.52<br />

Prob > F = 0.0000<br />

R-squared = 0.1002<br />

Adj R-squared = 0.0960<br />

Root MSE = .48648<br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard t statistic Prob<br />

error<br />

Age 0.004 0.004 0.96 0.34<br />

Age2 -0.000 0.000 -1.39 0.17<br />

Year of education -0.012*** 0.002 -5.42 0.00<br />

Household size -0.010** 0.005 -2.03 0.04<br />

Ethnicity 0.043* 0.024 1.77 0.08<br />

Percent child 0.001 0.000 1.45 0.15<br />

Percent elderly 0.000 0.000 -0.74 0.46<br />

Female head -0.049** 0.020 -2.43 0.02<br />

Electricity -0.002 0.020 -0.11 0.91<br />

Annual crop l<strong>and</strong> 0.000*** 0.000 6.37 0.00<br />

Perennial crop l<strong>and</strong> 0.000** 0.000 3.39 0.01<br />

Irrigated l<strong>and</strong> 0.000*** 0.000 6.66 0.00<br />

Road distance 0.003 0.003 -0.93 0.35<br />

Impassable road 0.010 0.007 1.58 0.11<br />

NU region -0.014 0.028 -0.50 0.61<br />

NCC region -0.112*** 0.027 -4.17 0.00<br />

SCC region -0.117*** 0.029 -4.01 0.00<br />

CH region -0.042 0.035 -1.19 0.24<br />

SE region -0.321*** 0.029 -10.87 0.00<br />

MRD region -0.258*** 0.028 -9.06 0.00<br />

constant 0.584*** 0.113 5.19 0.00<br />

Source: Econometric analysis of the 1998 VLSS.<br />

***Significant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level<br />

As shown in Table 3-36, very few of the explanatory variables are good at predicting the<br />

share of income from livestock production. Female-headed households rely less on livestock income,<br />

other things being equal, <strong>and</strong> households in the South Central Coast rely more on it. One reason for<br />

the inability to explain livestock income share is that the quality of the livestock income data is not as<br />

good as for other income sources. Animal purchases <strong>and</strong> sales are often large <strong>and</strong> infrequent<br />

transactions, so the measurement error is relatively high.<br />

The share of income from aquaculture, shown in Table 3-37, is positively related to distance<br />

to a paved road <strong>and</strong> negatively related to the number of months the road is impassable. If aquaculture<br />

is mainly for own consumption, then distance could force farmers to rely more on their own<br />

production rather than purchases, but it is difficult to explain the negative sign on the number of.<br />

Page 80


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Table 3-36. Linear regression model of shares of income from<br />

livestock production<br />

Dependent variable: Share of income of livestock production<br />

Number of obs = 4243<br />

F( 20, 4222) = 1.48<br />

Prob > F = 0.0765<br />

R-squared = 0.0070<br />

Adj R-squared = 0.0023<br />

Root MSE = .77069<br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard t statistic Prob<br />

error<br />

Age -0.000 0.007 -0.03 0.98<br />

Age2 0.000 0.000 0.09 0.93<br />

Year of education 0.007* 0.004 1.80 0.07<br />

Household size 0.005 0.008 0.58 0.56<br />

Ethnicity 0.031 0.039 0.81 0.42<br />

Percent child -0.001 0.001 -0.89 0.37<br />

Percent elderly 0.000 0.001 0.62 0.53<br />

Female head -0.064** 0.032 -2.01 0.05<br />

Electricity -0.039 0.031 -1.27 0.21<br />

Annual crop l<strong>and</strong> 0.000 0.000 0.56 0.58<br />

Perennial crop l<strong>and</strong> –0.000 0.000 -0.04 0.97<br />

Irrigated l<strong>and</strong> 0.000 0.000 0.09 0.93<br />

Road distance -0.004 0.004 -0.94 0.35<br />

Impassable road -0.015 0.010 -1.43 0.16<br />

NU region 0.062 0.045 1.37 0.17<br />

NCC region 0.083* 0.043 1.94 0.05<br />

SCC region 0.113** 0.046 2.45 0.01<br />

CH region 0.061 0.056 1.10 0.27<br />

SE region -0.019 0.047 -0.40 0.69<br />

MRD region 0.075* 0.045 1.66 0.10<br />

constant 0.049 0.178 -0.28 0.78<br />

Source: Econometric analysis of the 1998 VLSS.<br />

***Significant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level<br />

Table 3-37. Linear regression model of shares of income from<br />

aquaculture production<br />

Dependent variable: Share of income of aquaculture production<br />

Number of obs = 4243<br />

F( 20, 4222) = 18.58<br />

Prob > F = 0.0000<br />

R-squared = 0.0809<br />

Adj R-squared = 0.0765<br />

Root MSE = .14431<br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard t statistic Prob<br />

error<br />

Age 0.001 0.001 0.67 0.50<br />

Age2 -0.000 0.000 -0.99 0.32<br />

Years of education -0.001 0.001 -1.55 0.12<br />

Household size 0.000 0.001 0.40 0.69<br />

Ethnicity -0.021*** 0.007 -2.87 0.00<br />

Percent child -0.000 0.000 -0.02 0.98<br />

Percent elderly 0.000 0.000 0.15 0.88<br />

Female head -0.001 0.006 -0.16 0.88<br />

Electricity -0.005 0.006 -0.79 0.43<br />

Annual crop l<strong>and</strong> -0.000 0.000 -1.50 0.13<br />

Perennial crop l<strong>and</strong> –0.000 0.000 -0.04 0.97<br />

Irrigated l<strong>and</strong> -0.000 0.000 -0.91 0.36<br />

Road distance 0.013*** 0.001 16.25 0.00<br />

Impassable road -0.005*** 0.002 -2.73 0.01<br />

NU region 0.021** 0.008 2.56 0.01<br />

NCC region -0.012 0.008 -1.51 0.13<br />

SCC region -0.019** 0.009 -2.17 0.03<br />

CH region -0.020* 0.010 -1.91 0.06<br />

SE region -0.015* 0.009 -1.77 0.08<br />

MRD region 0.011 0.008 -1.26 0.21<br />

constant 0.023 0.033 0.70 0.49<br />

Source: Econometric analysis of the 1998 VLSS.<br />

***Significant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level<br />

Page 81


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

months of impassability. Ethnic minorities are less likely to earn a large share of their income from<br />

aquaculture, perhaps because of language barriers to extension assistance. After controlling other<br />

factors, the share of income from aquaculture is greater in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s than in most other<br />

regions.<br />

The share of income from forestry (including firewood sales) is higher among ethnic<br />

minorities than among Kinh <strong>and</strong> Hoa groups, though the size of the difference is small (2 percentage<br />

points). The l<strong>and</strong> coefficients indicate that the share of income from forestry is larger on large farms<br />

with little irrigation. Forestry income share is higher when the roads are impassable <strong>and</strong> when the<br />

household lives in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, the central coast, or the Southeast (see Table 3-38).<br />

The contribution of non-farm enterprises to rural household income is significantly lower<br />

among ethnic minorities, the gap being about 8 percentage points. Enterprise income is more<br />

important among rural households that have limited annual crop l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> among those with<br />

electricity. In fact, electricity is associated with a 10 percentage point increase in the share of income<br />

coming from non-farm enterprises (see Table 3-39). It should be noted, however, that electricity may<br />

be correlated with variables that are missing from the model such as the population density or income<br />

level of the commune but that are associated with non-farm enterprise opportunities. In this case, the<br />

coefficient on the electricity variable would overstate the effect of electrification on enterprise<br />

income.<br />

Table 3-38. Linear regression model of shares of income from forestry<br />

Dependent variable: Share of income of forestry<br />

Number of obs = 4243<br />

F( 20, 4222) = 31.26<br />

Prob > F = 0.0000<br />

R-squared = 0.1290<br />

Adj R-squared = 0.1249<br />

Root MSE = .05152<br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard t statistic Prob<br />

error<br />

Age 0.000 0.000 0.70 0.48<br />

Age2 -0.000 0.000 -0.53 0.60<br />

Years of education -0.000 0.000 1.16 0.24<br />

Household size -0.001* 0.001 -1.87 0.06<br />

Ethnicity 0.019*** 0.003 7.46 0.00<br />

Percent child 0.000 0.000 0.13 0.90<br />

Percent elderly 0.000* 0.000 1.78 0.08<br />

Female head -0.001 0.002 -0.45 0.65<br />

Electricity -0.019*** 0.002 -9.22 0.00<br />

Annual crop l<strong>and</strong> 0.000*** 0.000 3.02 0.00<br />

Perennial crop l<strong>and</strong> 0.000*** 0.000 6.46 0.00<br />

Irrigated l<strong>and</strong> -0.000*** 0.000 -2.82 0.00<br />

Road distance 0.000 0.000 1.28 0.20<br />

Impassable road 0.003*** 0.001 4.23 0.00<br />

NU region 0.023*** 0.003 7.77 0.00<br />

NCC region 0.023*** 0.003 8.21 0.00<br />

SCC region 0.012*** 0.003 3.90 0.00<br />

CH region -0.025*** 0.004 -6.71 0.00<br />

SE region 0.014*** 0.003 4.34 0.00<br />

MRD region 0.001 0.003 0.21 0.83<br />

constant 0.014 0.012 1.19 0.23<br />

Source: Econometric analysis of the 1998 VLSS.<br />

***Significant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level<br />

Page 82


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

Table 3-39. Linear regression model of shares of income from enterprises<br />

Dependent variable: Share of income of enterprises<br />

Number of obs = 4243<br />

F( 20, 4222) = 4.31<br />

Prob > F = 0.0000<br />

R-squared = 0.0200<br />

Adj R-squared = 0.0154<br />

Root MSE = .71553<br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard t statistic Prob<br />

error<br />

Age 0.001 0.006 0.16 0.88<br />

Age2 -0.000 0.000 -0.23 0.82<br />

Years of education -0.001 0.003 -0.41 0.68<br />

Household size 0.005 0.007 0.69 0.49<br />

Ethnicity -0.078** 0.036 -2.16 0.03<br />

Percent child 0.001 0.001 1.34 0.18<br />

Percent elderly -0.001 0.001 -1.49 0.14<br />

Female head 0.050* 0.029 1.69 0.09<br />

Electricity 0.100*** 0.029 3.46 0.00<br />

Annual crop l<strong>and</strong> -0.000** 0.000 -2.16 0.03<br />

Perennial crop l<strong>and</strong> –0.000 0.000 -1.08 0.28<br />

Irrigated l<strong>and</strong> -0.000 0.000 -1.59 0.11<br />

Road distance -0.001 0.004 -0.30 0.77<br />

Impassable road -0.014 0.010 1.40 0.16<br />

NU region -0.016 0.042 -0.38 0.71<br />

NCC region -0.007 0.040 -0.17 0.86<br />

SCC region -0.038 0.043 -0.88 0.38<br />

CH region 0.010 0.052 0.19 0.85<br />

SE region 0.157*** 0.043 3.61 0.00<br />

MRD region 0.077* 0.042 1.84 0.07<br />

constant 0.057 0.166 0.34 0.73<br />

Source: Econometric analysis of the 1998 VLSS.<br />

***Significant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level<br />

The contribution of wages to total income is significantly related to the age of the head of<br />

household. The coefficients indicate that the importance of wages is greater among the young heads<br />

<strong>and</strong> among the old heads, with the minimum occurring at around 58 years of age. Similarly, the share<br />

of wage income is greater among large households with few children or old people, with little annual<br />

or perennial l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> little irrigated l<strong>and</strong>. This is plausible since families may be “forced” into wage<br />

labor by limited access to l<strong>and</strong>, but it is also possible that households with wage income sell or rent<br />

out some of their l<strong>and</strong>. Not surprisingly, rural households in villages that are far from paved roads<br />

<strong>and</strong>/or on roads that are not open all year rely less on wage income than other households.<br />

Presumably, wage income opportunities are correlated with the density of economic activity, which is<br />

in turn associated with a good road network. The regional variables indicate that wage income is less<br />

important in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s than in the Red River Delta <strong>and</strong> less important than in all four<br />

southern regions (see Table 3-40)<br />

<strong>Income</strong> from other sources includes private transfers (gifts <strong>and</strong> remittances), public transfers<br />

(pensions <strong>and</strong> social assistance), rental income, interest income, <strong>and</strong> so on, but remittances are<br />

typically the most important category. The share of income from “other sources” is significantly<br />

greater among household with an educated head, few household members, a female head, a large<br />

proportion of older members, <strong>and</strong> little irrigated l<strong>and</strong> (see Table 3-41). These coefficient make sense<br />

if we think that pensions <strong>and</strong> social assistance more common among older individuals with limited<br />

means of production (e.g. irrigated l<strong>and</strong>). The fact that female-headed households earn a larger share<br />

Page 83


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

of their income from “other sources” probably reflects remittance income from the husb<strong>and</strong> who is<br />

working in the city or elsewhere away from the family.<br />

Table 3-40. Linear regression model of shares of income from wages<br />

Dependent variable: Share of income from wages<br />

Number of obs = 4243<br />

F( 20, 4222) = 34.00<br />

Prob > F = 0.0000<br />

R-squared = 0.1387<br />

Adj R-squared = 0.1346<br />

Root MSE = .255<br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard t statistic Prob<br />

error<br />

Age -0.008*** 0.002 -3.52 0.00<br />

Age2 0.000*** 0.000 3.10 0.00<br />

Years of education -0.002 0.001 1.30 0.19<br />

Household size 0.014*** 0.003 5.53 0.00<br />

Ethnicity 0.015 0.013 1.17 0.24<br />

Percent of child -0.001*** 0.000 -4.08 0.00<br />

Percent elderly -0.001*** 0.000 -5.98 0.00<br />

Female head 0.020* 0.010 1.93 0.05<br />

Electricity -0.049*** 0.010 -4.78 0.00<br />

Annual crop l<strong>and</strong> -0.000*** 0.000 -8.28 0.00<br />

Perennial crop l<strong>and</strong> –0.000*** 0.000 -5.82 0.00<br />

Irrigated l<strong>and</strong> -0.000*** 0.000 -4.62 0.00<br />

Road distance -0.007*** 0.001 -4.64 0.00<br />

Impassable road -0.011*** 0.003 -3.12 0.00<br />

NU region -0.068*** 0.015 -4.57 0.00<br />

NCC region 0.002 0.014 0.11 0.91<br />

SCC region 0.100*** 0.015 6.51 0.00<br />

CH region 0.043** 0.018 2.35 0.02<br />

SE region 0.182*** 0.015 11.77 0.00<br />

MRD region 0.126*** 0.015 8.42 0.00<br />

constant 0.388*** 0.059 6.57 0.00<br />

Source: Econometric analysis of the 1998 VLSS.<br />

***Significant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level<br />

Table 3-41. Linear regression model of shares of income from other sources<br />

Dependent variable: Share of income from other sources<br />

Number of obs = 4243<br />

F( 20, 4222) = 64.88<br />

Prob > F = 0.0000<br />

R-squared = 0.2351<br />

Adj R-squared = 0.2315<br />

Root MSE = .19713<br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard t statistic Prob<br />

error<br />

Age 0.002 0.002 1.08 0.28<br />

Age2 0.000 0.000 0.78 0.43<br />

Years of education 0.006*** 0.001 6.96 0.00<br />

Household size -0.014*** 0.002 -6.72 0.00<br />

Ethnicity -0.010 0.001 -1.06 0.29<br />

Percent child 0.000 0.000 0.32 0.75<br />

Percent elderly 0.002*** 0.000 11.96 0.00<br />

Female head 0.044*** 0.008 5.44 0.00<br />

Electricity 0.014* 0.008 1.82 0.07<br />

Annual crop l<strong>and</strong> 0.000 0.000 0.94 0.35<br />

Perennial crop l<strong>and</strong> 0.000 0.000 1.56 0.12<br />

Irrigated l<strong>and</strong> -0.000*** 0.000 -3.62 0.00<br />

Road distance 0.001 0.001 0.82 0.41<br />

Impassable road 0.004 0.003 1.54 0.12<br />

NU region -0.009 0.011 -0.75 0.45<br />

NCC region 0.023** 0.011 2.15 0.03<br />

SCC region -0.051*** 0.012 -4.31 0.00<br />

CH region -0.028* 0.014 -1.94 0.05<br />

SE region 0.003 0.012 0.23 0.82<br />

MRD region -0.009 0.012 -0.81 0.42<br />

constant -0.017 0.046 -0.37 0.71<br />

Source: Econometric analysis of the 1998 VLSS.<br />

***Significant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level<br />

Page 84


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

3.10 Summary<br />

The comparison of the three surveys indicates substantial growth in income <strong>and</strong> expenditure<br />

over 1993-98 <strong>and</strong> more modest but respectable growth over 1998-2002. The gains for rural<br />

households have been widespread across regions <strong>and</strong> types of households. In the rural Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s, per capita expenditure grew 32 percent between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998 <strong>and</strong> 11 percent between<br />

1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002, roughly equal to the national average for rural households. Although there is today a<br />

wider gap between poor <strong>and</strong> rich households than in 1993, paradoxically those who were poor in 1993<br />

gained as much on average as those who were “rich” in 1993. Thus, there is little evidence that the<br />

rural poor have, in general, been “left behind” in the rise in st<strong>and</strong>ards of living over the 1990s.<br />

At the same time, crop production continues to be the most important source of income for<br />

rural households, accounting for 38 percent of the net income in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. Poor rural<br />

households depend even more on crop income than other rural households. Staple food crops,<br />

particularly rice, continue to play a dominant role in crop production. Rice alone accounts for 46<br />

percent of the net value of crop production.<br />

One definition of diversification is based on the number of income sources <strong>and</strong> balance<br />

among them. Among rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, there is evidence of increased<br />

diversity in broad income categories, <strong>and</strong> well as increased diversity in crop production. It is also<br />

worth noting that diversity in crop production is generally higher among poor, rural households than<br />

among urban household or higher-income rural households. Farmers in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s have<br />

the most diverse cropping systems in Vietnam, growing over eight crops on average.<br />

If we define diversification in terms of the shift toward commercial production, the trend is<br />

unambiguous: households in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, as well as other rural areas, have shifted<br />

noticeably from subsistence production to commercial production. The share of crop production that<br />

is marketed rose from 22 percent to 34 percent in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> from 40 to 61 percent in<br />

rural areas as a whole. Although poor households are less market oriented, they also shifted toward<br />

commercial production over this period.<br />

If we define diversification in terms of the shift toward high-value crops, livestock, fisheries,<br />

<strong>and</strong> non-farm income sources, several conclusions emerge. There is evidence of crop diversification,<br />

with farmers reducing the area planted with rice <strong>and</strong> increasing the area planted to either sugarcane<br />

<strong>and</strong> fruit (according to the 1998 VLSS) or maize <strong>and</strong> tea (according to the 2002 VHLSS). Almost all<br />

rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s already raise livestock, but we do not see a consistent<br />

increase in the share of income from livestock production. The importance of fisheries has fallen<br />

somewhat in terms of the percentage of households participating <strong>and</strong> its contribution to total income,<br />

while that of forestry has increased. The importance of both activities, however, remains modest.<br />

Non-agricultural income among rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s accounted for 34<br />

percent of total income 2002, <strong>and</strong> it represented 37 percent of the growth in income between 1998 <strong>and</strong><br />

Page 85


Chapter 3. Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

2002. Thus, non-farm income is important in the livelihoods of rural households, but it’s importance<br />

grew only slowly over the period 1993-2002. The importance of self-employment in family-owned<br />

enterprises has fallen, perhaps due to consolidation, while that of wage labor has increased.<br />

Over 1993-1998, the growth in crop income accounted for 45 percent of the growth in overall<br />

income for the average rural household in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, but crop income contributes an even<br />

higher percentage (69 percent) among the poorest rural households. Decomposing crop income<br />

growth, 40 percent is attributable to higher yields, 28 percent to higher real prices, <strong>and</strong> 6 percent to<br />

crop diversification (defined as the reallocation of sown crop l<strong>and</strong>). Nationally, crop diversification<br />

accounts for 12 percent of the growth in crop income. The sources of crop income growth vary<br />

across income groups. Poor households increased their crop income largely by achieving higher<br />

yields, particularly for rice, while richer households increased their incomes by exp<strong>and</strong>ing the area<br />

cultivated. The contribution of diversification shows an erratic pattern across income categories, but<br />

appears to be less important for poor rural households than others.<br />

Page 86


CHAPTER FOUR<br />

ANALYSIS OF FOOD DEMAND 1<br />

4.1 Introduction<br />

One of the driving forces behind income <strong>and</strong> crop diversification is economic growth <strong>and</strong> the<br />

associated shifts in the composition of consumer dem<strong>and</strong>. Engel’s Law, one of the most consistent<br />

patterns found in economics, states that as income rises, the share of the budget spent on food tends to<br />

decline. A related pattern is Bennett’s Law, which states that, as income rises, consumers reallocate<br />

their food budget away from starchy staples, such as rice <strong>and</strong> maize, that are inexpensive sources of<br />

calories, toward higher-cost sources of calories such as fruits, vegetables, <strong>and</strong> animal products. As the<br />

economy grows <strong>and</strong> incomes rise, the domestic dem<strong>and</strong> for non-food goods <strong>and</strong> services rises faster<br />

than the dem<strong>and</strong> for food, <strong>and</strong> the dem<strong>and</strong> for fruits, vegetables, <strong>and</strong> animal products rises faster than<br />

the dem<strong>and</strong> for grains <strong>and</strong> tubers. Of course, food consumption patterns are also affected by changes<br />

in relative prices, cultural factors, religious restrictions, <strong>and</strong> demographic shifts, such as urbanization.<br />

And diversification is driven by factors other than income growth, factors such as falling barriers to<br />

international trade, improvements in transportation infrastructure, <strong>and</strong> new agricultural technology.<br />

Nonetheless, income growth is probably the main factor affecting trends in food consumption <strong>and</strong><br />

domestic dem<strong>and</strong> is one of the most important drivers of income <strong>and</strong> crop diversification.<br />

Differences in food dem<strong>and</strong> across income categories at one point in time can provide clues to<br />

the changes in dem<strong>and</strong> that will result from sustained economic growth. In particular, household<br />

survey data can be used to identify the effect of price <strong>and</strong> income on the dem<strong>and</strong> for different<br />

commodities. This section describes an analysis of the 1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey to<br />

assess the impact of income, price, <strong>and</strong> other factors on food dem<strong>and</strong>. By studying the differences<br />

between the spending patterns of high-income <strong>and</strong> low-income Vietnamese household at one time, we<br />

can better underst<strong>and</strong> the likely pace of growth of domestic dem<strong>and</strong> as incomes rise.<br />

4.2 Methods<br />

In this study, we use an approximation of the Almost Ideal Dem<strong>and</strong> System, proposed by<br />

Deaton <strong>and</strong> Muelbauer (1980), applied to a system of 14 food products or categories. In this model,<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> is represented by the budget share of each commodity, while prices <strong>and</strong> income are expressed<br />

in logarithms. The model has been widely applied in dem<strong>and</strong> analysis because it has some convenient<br />

features. First, if the system of equations is complete (the actual budget shares sum to 1.0), then the<br />

predicted budget shares will also sum to 1.0, a featured known as adding up. In addition, it is<br />

1<br />

An econometric analysis of the supply of four major crops was also carried out. Although the results<br />

were not satisfactory, possibly due to the type of price data available, the method <strong>and</strong> results are presented in<br />

Annex A.<br />

Page 87


Chapter 4. Analysis of food dem<strong>and</strong><br />

relatively easy to impose or test for symmetry in the cross-price terms 2 . Third, the equation is<br />

consistent with economic theory in that the dem<strong>and</strong> equation can be derived from a well-behaved<br />

utility function.<br />

This analysis uses a variant of the AIDS model that takes the following form:<br />

s<br />

= α +<br />

∑<br />

i<br />

β<br />

i<br />

⎛ x ⎞<br />

ln(pi<br />

) + δln⎜<br />

⎟ +<br />

⎝ P ⎠<br />

⎛ x ⎞<br />

⎝ P ⎠<br />

∑ θ<br />

jD<br />

j<br />

ln⎜<br />

⎟ + ∑γ<br />

kZk<br />

+<br />

j<br />

where s is the budget share of a given food commodity,<br />

p i is the price of commodity i,<br />

x is a measure of household welfare, typically per capita income or per capita<br />

expenditure,<br />

P is the price index reflecting the cost of living where the household lives,<br />

D j is one of a set of dummy variable indicating the location (urban or rural) or region,<br />

Z k is one of a set of household characteristics,<br />

e is the error term, reflecting idiosyncratic factors affecting dem<strong>and</strong>,<br />

<strong>and</strong> α, β, δ, θ <strong>and</strong> γ are parameters estimated by the model.<br />

The prices (p i ) used in this analysis are community prices, collected as part of the Community<br />

Price Survey, at the time of the household survey. For the heterogeneous categories such as fruits <strong>and</strong><br />

vegetables, we construct a price index based on the 2-4 most important commodities within that<br />

category. As a proxy for per capita income (x), we use the value of per capita consumption<br />

expenditure, including the value of home produced food <strong>and</strong> the rental equivalent of owner-occupied<br />

housing <strong>and</strong> consumer durable goods. The price index (P), in order to be consistent with an explicit<br />

utility function, should be a complex non-linear expression. Most analysts use a linear approximation<br />

of the price index to simplify estimation. Here, we use the price index constructed by the General<br />

Statistics Office for the 1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey, based on the prices in the<br />

Community Price Survey. Because it is likely that the relationship between income <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong><br />

varies across regions <strong>and</strong> between urban <strong>and</strong> rural areas, we include an set of interaction terms that<br />

combine real per capita expenditure (ln(x/P)) with an urban dummy <strong>and</strong> regional dummy variables<br />

(D j ). The household characteristics (Z k ) used in this analysis are the size of the household, the<br />

proportion of older adults (over 60 years), the proportion of children (under 10 years), a dummy for<br />

female-headed households, the number of years of education of the head of household, a dummy<br />

variable for urban households, <strong>and</strong> a set of dummy variables for the region.<br />

This equation is applied to each of the 14 food commodities or food categories. By excluding<br />

non-food items from the model, we are implicitly assuming that the dem<strong>and</strong> for food <strong>and</strong> non-food are<br />

weaky separable, meaning that consumer decisions on food are unaffected by non-food prices, except<br />

to the extent that they affect real income. The fourteen equations can be estimated independently<br />

under two conditions: a) if we use the same explanatory variables in each equation or b) if we do not<br />

k<br />

e<br />

2<br />

According to dem<strong>and</strong> theory, dem<strong>and</strong> systems based on rational behavior should be symmetric,<br />

meaning that the effect of a one unit increase in the price of good i on the dem<strong>and</strong> for good j should be equal to<br />

the effect of a one unit increase in the price of good j on the dem<strong>and</strong> for good i.<br />

Page 88


Chapter 4. Analysis of food dem<strong>and</strong><br />

wish to impose any cross-equations restrictions on the system of equations. In this case, the<br />

explanatory variables are the same in each equation but we wish to impose symmetry in the crossprice<br />

effects. In a system with 14 commodity categories, symmetry requires imposing 91 restrictions<br />

on the estimated coefficients 3 Thus, the system of equations is estimated simultaneously by applying<br />

Zellner’s seemingly unrelated regression.<br />

<strong>Income</strong> elasticities can be calculated from the estimated coefficients using the following<br />

expression:<br />

δ + θ j D j<br />

η = 1+<br />

s<br />

where η is the income elasticity, or more precisely, the elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong> with respect to<br />

per capita consumption expenditure <strong>and</strong> the other variables are as defined above. The Hicksian<br />

(compensated) price elasticities can be calculated as follows:<br />

ε<br />

H<br />

ij<br />

β<br />

=<br />

s<br />

ij<br />

i<br />

+ s<br />

i<br />

− Θ<br />

where ε H ij is the Hicksian price elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong> for commodity i with respect to the price<br />

of commodity j, β ij is the coefficient on the price of commodity j in the dem<strong>and</strong> equation for<br />

commodity i, Θ is a Kroenecker delta, which takes the value of 1 for the own-price elasticity (when<br />

i=j) <strong>and</strong> 0 for cross-price elasticities (when i≠j), <strong>and</strong> the other variables are as defined above. The<br />

Marshallian (uncompensated) price elasticities are obtained as follows:<br />

ε<br />

ij<br />

β<br />

=<br />

s<br />

i<br />

i<br />

+ s<br />

i<br />

− Θ − η s<br />

where η i s j is the income effect.<br />

i<br />

j<br />

4.3 Results<br />

With 14 equations <strong>and</strong> 35 explanatory variables per equation, the analysis of food dem<strong>and</strong><br />

generates 490 estimated coefficients, many of which are difficult to interpret by themselves. Thus, we<br />

summarize the results, focusing on the effect of income <strong>and</strong> prices on food dem<strong>and</strong>. As shown in<br />

Table 4-1, the explanatory power of the independent variables is not very strong, except in the case of<br />

rice. Based on the values of the R 2 , the equation “explains” 70 percent of the variation in rice budget<br />

shares, but most of the other commodities the equations explain between 10 <strong>and</strong> 20 percent of the<br />

variation. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the expenditure coefficient is statistically significant in 9 of the 14<br />

equations 4 . Because the budget share (not the quantity consumed) is the dependent variable, a<br />

positive <strong>and</strong> statistically significant expenditure coefficient means that the budget share rises with<br />

3<br />

In a 14 x 14 matrix, there are 91 pairs of off-diagonal elements that are forced to be equal. This is<br />

calculated as (14x14 – 14)/2.<br />

4<br />

A t-statistic whose absolute value is 1.97 or greater means that the coefficient is significantly<br />

different than zero at the 95 percent confidence level.<br />

Page 89


Chapter 4. Analysis of food dem<strong>and</strong><br />

total expenditure, implying that the expenditure elasticity is greater than one <strong>and</strong> the commodity is a<br />

“luxury” good. This is the case for “other grains” (which includes processed grain products such as<br />

bread <strong>and</strong> pasta), meat, beverages, <strong>and</strong> “other food” (which includes many processed foods <strong>and</strong> meals<br />

consumed outside the home). A negative coefficient implies that the budget share declines with<br />

higher total expenditure, so the expenditure elasticity is less than one. This is the case for rice,<br />

cassava, fruit, fish, cooking <strong>and</strong> oil. When the expenditure coefficient is not statistically significant,<br />

then we cannot say that the expenditure elasticity is different than one.<br />

The urban-expenditure interaction term tells us whether the effect of higher expenditure on<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> is different in urban areas. Nine of the 14 commodities have significantly different<br />

expenditure-dem<strong>and</strong> patterns in urban areas.<br />

The expenditure elasticity is calculated using the formula described above, evaluating the<br />

budget share (s) <strong>and</strong> the location dummy variables (D j ) at their mean values. For rice, the expenditure<br />

elasticity is 0.306, implying that a 10 percent increase in overall household expenditure would be<br />

associated with an increase of about 3 percent in rice dem<strong>and</strong>. This is consistent with Bennett’s Law<br />

<strong>and</strong> the international patterns discussed above in which the budget share allocated to starchy staple<br />

foods declines as income (expenditure) rises. The expenditure elasticity of cassava is negative,<br />

suggesting that a 10 percent increase in total expenditure leads to a 19 percent decrease in cassava<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>. In other words, for the average household in Vietnam, cassava is an “inferior good”, in<br />

economic terms. Fruit, fish, <strong>and</strong> cooking oil are like rice in that the elasticitiy is between zero <strong>and</strong><br />

one, implying that dem<strong>and</strong> rises with higher income but less than proportionately. For maize, sweet<br />

potatoes, legumes, <strong>and</strong> vegetables, the coefficient is not statistically significant, so we cannot say the<br />

elasticity is different than one. And in the case of meat, beverages, “other grains,” <strong>and</strong> “other food,”<br />

the expenditure elasticities are significantly greater than one, implying that the dem<strong>and</strong> for these<br />

goods will rise faster than income.<br />

Table 4-1. Effect of expenditure on food dem<strong>and</strong><br />

Food Expenditure Urban-expend Expend<br />

category coeff T stat coeff T stat elast R2<br />

Rice -0.160 -38.458 0.059 16.045 0.306 0.704<br />

Maize 0.000 0.053 0.004 5.794 -0.531 0.188<br />

Other grains 0.007 5.641 -0.011 -10.258 1.227 0.082<br />

Cassava -0.002 -3.491 0.005 8.853 -1.885 0.136<br />

Sw pot -0.000 -1.078 0.001 4.022 0.346 0.120<br />

Legumes 0.001 1.282 -0.000 -0.380 1.175 0.075<br />

Fruit -0.009 -8.089 -0.001 -1.049 0.589 0.165<br />

Veg -0.001 -1.192 -0.005 -7.333 0.748 0.179<br />

Meat 0.025 7.470 -0.021 -7.005 1.240 0.151<br />

Fish -0.018 -7.605 -0.010 -4.834 0.870 0.157<br />

Sugar -0.001 -1.131 -0.004 -6.584 1.091 0.109<br />

Oil -0.004 -5.428 -0.001 -1.027 0.693 0.128<br />

Beverage 0.003 2.296 -0.000 -0.200 1.172 0.108<br />

Oth food 0.017 4.061 -0.005 -1.498 1.256 0.216<br />

Source: Econometric analysis of the 1998 VLSS.<br />

The effect of the price of each commodity on its own dem<strong>and</strong> is summarized in Table 4-2.<br />

Eight of the 14 equations have price coefficients that are statistically significant at the 95 percent<br />

Page 90


Chapter 4. Analysis of food dem<strong>and</strong><br />

level, implying that the price elasticities are significantly different than –1. The (Marshallian) price<br />

elasticity for rice is –0.481, meaning that if the price of rice increased by 10 percent, the dem<strong>and</strong> for<br />

rice would fall about 4.8 percent 5 . The dem<strong>and</strong> for cassava, sweet potatoes, <strong>and</strong> “other grains” is<br />

highly responsive to price, perhaps because as staples they are consumed strictly because they are<br />

economical. Small changes in relative prices which remove that price advantage have large effects on<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>. The dem<strong>and</strong> for “other grains,” sugar, oil, <strong>and</strong> “other foods” is much less price elastic. It<br />

should be noted that community prices are only an approximation of the prices that households<br />

actually face. According to econometric theory, measurement error in the explanatory variables<br />

introduces a bias toward zero in the estimated coefficients. In this model, a bias toward zero in the<br />

coefficients implies a bias toward –1 in the estimated own-price elasticity. This may explain the large<br />

number of elasticity estimated clustered close to –1 (see the results for legumes, fruit, vegetables, <strong>and</strong><br />

meat).<br />

Table 4-2. Effect of prices on food dem<strong>and</strong><br />

Food Price Hicks p Marsh p<br />

category coeff T stat elast elast<br />

Rice 0.077 11.197 -0.418 -0.481<br />

Maize -0.001 -1.781 -1.633 -1.632<br />

Grains 0.009 3.856 -0.404 -0.422<br />

Cassava -0.001 -2.380 -1.734 -1.731<br />

Sw pot -0.001 -4.225 -1.497 -1.498<br />

Legumes -0.000 -0.019 -0.984 -1.004<br />

Fruit 0.001 0.780 -0.942 -0.957<br />

Veg 0.001 0.581 -0.924 -0.934<br />

Meat 0.012 1.340 -0.776 -0.906<br />

Fish -0.008 -2.638 -1.113 -1.157<br />

Sugar 0.008 2.929 -0.401 -0.416<br />

Oil 0.012 4.851 -0.099 -0.108<br />

Beverage -0.005 -1.737 -1.198 -1.222<br />

Oth food 0.036 6.490 -0.388 -0.471<br />

Source: Econometric analysis of the 1998 VLSS.<br />

The effect of selected household characteristics on consumer dem<strong>and</strong> is presented in Table 4-<br />

3. The coefficients on the urban dummy variable suggest that, other things being equal, urban<br />

households spend a significantly smaller share of their budgets on rice, maize, sweet potatoes, <strong>and</strong><br />

cassava than rural households do. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, urban households spend a significantly larger<br />

share of their budgets on meat, fish, <strong>and</strong> sugar than rural households.<br />

Female-headed households spend less on maize <strong>and</strong> sweet potatoes <strong>and</strong> more on legumes,<br />

meat, fish, <strong>and</strong> sugar than male-headed households, other factors being equal. These differences do<br />

not necessarily reflect gender differences in tastes but may also reflect differences in the age of the<br />

heads of households (many of the female heads are widows), availability of labor, or other differences<br />

between male- <strong>and</strong> female-headed households.<br />

5<br />

The Marshallian (or uncompensated) price elasticity refers to the effect of a change in prices on<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>, holding nominal income constant. The Hicksian (or compensated) price elasticity refers to the effect of<br />

a change in prices on dem<strong>and</strong>, holding real income (or utility) constant). Except for items that account for a<br />

large share of the budget, such as rice, the difference between the Marshallian <strong>and</strong> Hicksian own-price<br />

elasticities is usually small.<br />

Page 91


Chapter 4. Analysis of food dem<strong>and</strong><br />

The size <strong>and</strong> age-composition of the household also have statistically significant effects on<br />

budget allocations. In many cases, the signs of the coefficients do not have obvious interpretations<br />

nor immediate policy implications, but it is important to control for these factors in order to improve<br />

the quality of the estimated price <strong>and</strong> income coefficients.<br />

Table 4-3. Effect of household characteristics on food dem<strong>and</strong><br />

Food Urban area Female head Household size Pct elderly Pct children<br />

category Coeff T stat Coeff T stat Coeff T stat Coeff T stat Coeff T stat<br />

Rice -0.025 -4.22 0.004 0.86 0.009 1.51 0.005 0.99 -0.065 -9.29<br />

Maize -0.017 -15.31 -0.003 -3.13 -0.001 -0.48 -0.010 -10.09 -0.003 -2.65<br />

Grains -0.001 -0.44 0.000 0.22 -0.001 -0.47 0.002 1.15 0.002 1.02<br />

Cassava -0.003 -2.86 -0.002 -1.88 -0.001 -0.79 -0.015 -16.89 -0.002 -1.29<br />

Sw pot -0.002 -3.83 -0.002 -4.45 -0.005 -10.11 -0.001 -2.34 0.001 1.93<br />

Legumes 0.002 1.64 0.005 4.64 0.004 2.79 0.002 1.66 -0.000 -0.26<br />

Fruit 0.002 1.12 0.001 0.59 -0.000 -0.19 -0.007 -4.97 0.006 3.26<br />

Veg -0.002 -1.75 -0.000 -0.09 -0.001 -0.72 0.002 2.02 0.001 0.57<br />

Meat 0.018 3.72 0.009 2.29 0.015 3.12 -0.001 -0.18 0.005 0.82<br />

Fish 0.016 4.63 0.021 7.44 0.013 3.67 0.031 9.81 0.025 6.11<br />

Sugar 0.007 7.18 0.004 4.74 0.004 4.74 0.006 6.38 0.005 4.41<br />

Oil -0.002 -1.58 0.000 0.54 0.002 1.98 0.001 1.10 0.003 2.35<br />

Beverage -0.004 -1.72 0.003 1.79 0.002 1.02 0.003 1.36 -0.018 -6.95<br />

Oth food -0.011 -1.97 0.002 0.46 -0.006 -1.03 0.012 2.32 0.005 0.71<br />

Source: Econometric analysis of the 1998 VLSS.<br />

The equations used in this analysis are flexible with regard to urban-rural differences in<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>, since there are both urban dummy variables that can shift the dem<strong>and</strong> curve, the interaction<br />

terms between the urban dummy variable <strong>and</strong> per capita expenditure allow the effect of higher total<br />

expenditure on dem<strong>and</strong> to vary between urban <strong>and</strong> rural households. Table 4-4 gives the estimated<br />

expenditure <strong>and</strong> (Marshallian) price elasticities evaluated for average urban <strong>and</strong> rural households. As<br />

a rule, the expenditure elasticities are generally higher among rural households than among urban<br />

households. This is presumably the result of the fact that rural households are generally poorer, so<br />

they spend a larger share of any additional income on food. Urban households are more likely to be<br />

close to saturation with food consumption <strong>and</strong> will allocate a larger share of additional income to nonfood<br />

items. Price elasticities also differ between urban <strong>and</strong> rural households, although there is no<br />

discernable pattern.<br />

Table 4-4. Urban <strong>and</strong> rural dem<strong>and</strong> elasticities<br />

Food Exp. elasticities Price elasticities<br />

category Urban Rural Urban Rural<br />

Rice 0.100 0.344 -0.205 -0.523<br />

Maize -0.965 -0.512 -5.346 -1.468<br />

Grains 0.745 1.497 -0.529 -0.362<br />

Cassava -0.657 -1.939 -6.100 -1.540<br />

Sw pot 0.486 0.322 -1.993 -1.414<br />

Legumes 1.136 1.196 -1.004 -1.004<br />

Fruit 0.521 0.613 -0.953 -0.958<br />

Veg 0.379 0.872 -0.921 -0.938<br />

Meat 1.096 1.302 -0.896 -0.910<br />

Fish 0.699 0.931 -1.166 -1.155<br />

Sugar 0.881 1.163 -0.337 -0.443<br />

Oil 0.573 0.730 0.112 -0.174<br />

Beverage 1.185 1.167 -1.252 -1.212<br />

Oth food 1.123 1.370 -0.673 -0.295<br />

Source: Econometric analysis of the 1998 VLSS.<br />

Page 92


Chapter 4. Analysis of food dem<strong>and</strong><br />

Because this report focuses on the patterns of income <strong>and</strong> crop diversification in the Northen<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s, we present the expenditure <strong>and</strong> own-price elasticities for this region in Table 4-5. In some<br />

ways, the results are similar to the results for the average in Vietnam, presented in Table 4-1 <strong>and</strong><br />

Table 4-2: the expenditure elasticity of rice is low but positive; meat, beverages, “other grains,” <strong>and</strong><br />

“other food” have expenditure elasticities greater than one; <strong>and</strong> the dem<strong>and</strong> for cassava is relatively<br />

income inelastic. Some differences can be noted, however. The expenditure elasticity of rice is<br />

higher in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s than in the rest of country, <strong>and</strong>, although cassava dem<strong>and</strong> is relatively<br />

income-inelastic, higher incomes among households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s are associated with<br />

higher cassava dem<strong>and</strong>, not lower. These differences are consistent with the fact that the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s is a poorer region, spending a larger share of any additional income on starchy staple foods<br />

<strong>and</strong> less on high-cost sources of calories <strong>and</strong> non-food items.<br />

Table 4-5. Expenditure <strong>and</strong> own-price elasticities of<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Food<br />

category<br />

Expenditure<br />

elasticities<br />

Own-price<br />

elasticities<br />

Rice 0.480 -0.542<br />

Maize 1.106 -1.162<br />

Grains 1.332 -0.380<br />

Casasava 0.493 -1.439<br />

Sw pot 0.966 -1.352<br />

Legumes 1.080 -1.006<br />

Fruit 0.600 -0.955<br />

Veg 0.900 -0.952<br />

Meat 1.155 -0.895<br />

Fish 0.337 -1.256<br />

Sugar 0.870 -0.330<br />

Oil 0.757 -0.306<br />

Beverage 1.125 -1.164<br />

Oth food 1.433 -0.046<br />

Source: Econometric analysis of the 1998 VLSS.<br />

In summary, the analysis of dem<strong>and</strong> patterns in the 1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey<br />

confirms that the dem<strong>and</strong> for meat, beverages, <strong>and</strong> processed foods are more income-elastic than other<br />

foods. More specifically, if dem<strong>and</strong> patterns across households can be extrapolated to trends in<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> over time, rising household income will cause the dem<strong>and</strong> for meat, beverages, <strong>and</strong> processed<br />

foods to rise the fastest, followed by fish, vegetables, <strong>and</strong> fruits. The growth in the dem<strong>and</strong> for rice<br />

<strong>and</strong> sweet potatoes will be modest <strong>and</strong> the dem<strong>and</strong> for cassava (for human consumption) can be<br />

expected to decline as incomes rise.<br />

Two qualifications regarding the results of the dem<strong>and</strong> analysis should be mentioned. First,<br />

in using these results to predict how dem<strong>and</strong> will change in response to income growth, we are<br />

assuming that, as Vietnamese households earn higher incomes, they will adopt the spending patterns<br />

of households that have higher incomes today. Second, the analysis predicts the effect of prices <strong>and</strong><br />

income on the dem<strong>and</strong> for food for human consumption. It does not include the dem<strong>and</strong> for food for<br />

industrial purposes, for livestock feed, or for export. Thus, the dem<strong>and</strong> for maize will probably grow<br />

Page 93


Chapter 4. Analysis of food dem<strong>and</strong><br />

more rapidly than suggested by its income elasticity because maize is used for animal feed, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> for animal products will increase rapidly as incomes rise.<br />

Page 94


CHAPTER FIVE<br />

INCOME DIVERSIFICATION FROM THE FARMERS’ PERSPECTIVES<br />

The analysis of the Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Surveys provides a detailed picture of how<br />

diversification has contributed to rural income growth over the period 1993-98, <strong>and</strong> the social<br />

accounting matrix for the northern upl<strong>and</strong> mountain region illustrates the linkages between<br />

diversification sectors than other sectors of the economy. But these two types of analysis are not able<br />

to examine the “how” <strong>and</strong> “why” of income diversification at the household level, nor the role played<br />

by traders, processors, <strong>and</strong> various levels of government. The purpose of the Qualitative Social<br />

Assessment was to examine the process of income diversification to identify constraints <strong>and</strong><br />

opportunities as perceived by several key participants in the process: local government officials,<br />

traders <strong>and</strong> processors, <strong>and</strong> farm households themselves. Thus, the Qualitative Social Assessment of<br />

<strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> (QSAID) included four surveys: provincial authorities, district authorities,<br />

commune authorities, rural households, <strong>and</strong> traders. This section describes the methods <strong>and</strong> results of<br />

the QSAID survey of rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region.<br />

5.1 Methods<br />

5.1.1 Questionnaire<br />

The questionnaire used in the QSAID Household Survey was ten pages long, including the<br />

cover sheet (the household questionnaire is provided in Appendix B). It contains a mix of quantitative<br />

questions such as size of farm <strong>and</strong> qualitative questions such as whether the st<strong>and</strong>ard of living of the<br />

household has improved or deteriorated. Somewhat more than half the questions were closed,<br />

meaning that the enumerator records a number or classifies the answer using pre-determined codes.<br />

Other questions, such as “why” questions were left open <strong>and</strong> the responses were recorded in notes.<br />

The questionnaire had five sections:<br />

• Section A covered the characteristics <strong>and</strong> living conditions of the household, including<br />

access to l<strong>and</strong>, housing characteristics, ownership of selected consumer goods, perceived<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard of living relative to others in the village, <strong>and</strong> perceived changes in st<strong>and</strong>ard of<br />

living over time.<br />

• Section B focused on the income sources of the household, including which sources have<br />

become more or less important over time <strong>and</strong> perceptions of the important income sources<br />

of others in the village.<br />

• Section C examined the perceptions <strong>and</strong> experience regarding income diversification,<br />

concentrating on attempts to grow new crops or launch new income-generating activities.<br />

• Section D explored the role of traders <strong>and</strong> processors, evaluating the degree of<br />

competition in agricultural markets <strong>and</strong> the relationship between farmers <strong>and</strong> buyers.<br />

Page 95


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

• And Section E asked about the role of the government in promoting new crops <strong>and</strong> new<br />

activities, including questions about the types of assistance offered, the usefulness of this<br />

assistance, <strong>and</strong> how the government could best contribute to income diversification <strong>and</strong><br />

poverty reduction.<br />

Many of the questions ask about changes in livelihoods over time. After discussions with our<br />

Vietnamese colleagues <strong>and</strong> field testing the questionnaire, it was decided to use 1994 as the base year.<br />

The recall period (eight years) is long enough to capture structural changes in the agricultural<br />

economy, but short enough to ensure that respondents can recall their main sources of income. We<br />

also wanted to include younger households that may not have been formed before 1994. More than<br />

90 percent of the heads of household in our sample are at least 28 years old, implying that they would<br />

have been a head of household in 1994 or at least aware of household income sources 1 .<br />

5.1.2 Sampling <strong>and</strong> data collection<br />

For the purpose of this study, the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region is defined as the 14 provinces in the<br />

Northeast <strong>and</strong> the Northwest regions. The QSAID Farmer Survey used a five-stage stratified cluster<br />

sample using purposive sampling. In the first stage, eight provinces were selected to represent the<br />

diversity of the region in terms of market access (proximity to Hanoi), topography (lowl<strong>and</strong> vs.<br />

upl<strong>and</strong>), <strong>and</strong> geography (east vs. west). In the second stage, we selected two districts from each of the<br />

eight provinces. Generally speaking, one district was chosen close to the main roads or a major city<br />

while the other was more remote. The selection also took into account the ethnic composition of the<br />

districts in order to ensure that the districts were representative of the province. In the third stage, one<br />

commune was selected r<strong>and</strong>omly in each of the 16 selected districts (see Table 5-1 <strong>and</strong> Figure 5-1).<br />

While the province, district, <strong>and</strong> commune selections were made by the survey management<br />

before the data collection was launched, the selection of villages <strong>and</strong> households was carried out by<br />

the field teams. The data collection was carried out by two teams, each consisting of one supervisor<br />

<strong>and</strong> two researchers. The teams selected two villages in each of the 16 selected communes for a total<br />

of 32 villages. The teams were instructed to select villages that were representative of the commune<br />

in terms of income, ethnicity, <strong>and</strong> level of accessibility. In particular, they were asked to avoid the<br />

tendency to visit “model” villages or easily accessed villages.<br />

In the fifth <strong>and</strong> last stage of sample, the survey teams selected between 5 <strong>and</strong> 10 households<br />

to interview. The number of households was left open, depending on resource <strong>and</strong> time constraints,<br />

but in practice, the teams were able to interview 10 households in most of the villages. The teams<br />

used village leaders to help select households, but they were instructed that the households should be<br />

representative of the village in terms of income, ethnicity, <strong>and</strong> level of accessibility. In particular, the<br />

1 In some cases, the respondent may be comparing the income patterns of their own household now<br />

with that of their parents in 1994.<br />

Page 96


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

teams were asked to avoid the tendency to over-sample households that are richer, more accessible, or<br />

Kinh. Overall, 307 households were interviewed.<br />

Table 5-1: Provinces, districts, <strong>and</strong> communes selected for Qualitative Social Assessment<br />

of <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

Province<br />

code<br />

Province<br />

District/<br />

commune<br />

code<br />

District Commune Hardship<br />

factor<br />

1 Yen Bai 1 Tram Tau Xa Ho 0.7<br />

1 Yen Bai 2 Tran Yen Luong Thinh 0.3<br />

2 Ha Giang 1 Dong Van Van Chai 0.7<br />

2 Ha Giang 2 Vi Xuyen Viet Lam 0.5<br />

3 Lang Son 1 Dinh Lap Cuong Loi 0.4<br />

3 Lang Son 2 Van Quan Trang Phat 0.3<br />

4 Bac Giang 1 Luc Ngan Bien Son 0.1<br />

4 Bac Giang 2 Luc Nam Nghia Phuong 0.1<br />

5 Thai Nguyen 1 Phu Luong Phan Me 0.1<br />

5 Thai Nguyen 2 Vo Nhai Dan Tien 0.4<br />

6 Bac Kan 1 Ngan Son Thuong Quan 0.7<br />

6 Bac Kan 2 Choi Moi Nong Ha 0.3<br />

7 Son La 1 Yen Chau Phieng Khoai 0.5<br />

7 Son La 2 Thuan Chau Muong Khieng 0.5<br />

8 Lai Chau 1 Muang Lay Cha To 0.5<br />

8 Lai Chau 2 Dien Bien Dong Keo Lom 0.7<br />

The interviews were carried out using a semi-structured 9-page questionnaire. About twothirds<br />

of the questions were closed-ended, meaning that the responses were classified into predetermined<br />

codes. The other third of the questions were open-ended, allowing the respondent to<br />

answer in any form. The responses were recorded either in notebooks or on the back of the<br />

questionnaire. The interviews were generally at the home of the respondent. In order to reduce the<br />

risk of outside influence, the interviews were carried out without neighbors <strong>and</strong> village representatives<br />

whenever possible.<br />

Later, the data were computerized using a data entry program written in MS Access. The<br />

program was designed to replicate the layout of the questionnaire <strong>and</strong> included range checks to<br />

minimize data entry error. The data files were then converted to Stata for processing <strong>and</strong> analysis.<br />

5.1.3 Measures of income <strong>and</strong> accessibility<br />

Because the focus of the study is on the role of income diversification in reducing poverty, we<br />

are interested in how the experience of the rural poor differs from other rural households. We do not<br />

attempt to collect all the information necessary to estimate income or expenditure directly. Rather, we<br />

construct<br />

Page 97


Figure 5-1. Location of provinces, districts, <strong>and</strong> communes included in QSAID<br />

Source: Spatial analysis of GIS data from the Center for Remote Sensing & Geomatics.


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

an index of household st<strong>and</strong>ard of living based on the characteristics of the head of household,<br />

household size <strong>and</strong> composition, housing characteristics, <strong>and</strong> ownership of selected consumer goods.<br />

The weights used to combine these indicators into one index are based on econometric analysis of the<br />

1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey (VLSS). This analysis allows us to identify the relationship<br />

between per capita expenditure <strong>and</strong> the indicators (the method is described in more detail in Appendix<br />

D). We use this index of household st<strong>and</strong>ard of living to divide the sample into terciles (three equalsized<br />

groups). Although these groups actually represent terciles of estimated per capita consumption<br />

expenditure based on household characteristics, we refer to them as “income terciles” or “income<br />

categories” for convenience. Although we refer to lower-income tercile <strong>and</strong> higher-income tercile, it<br />

should be kept in mind that even the households in the “high-income” tercile are poor by international<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>and</strong> even compared to other households in Vietnam. Their incomes are “high” only relative<br />

to other rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region.<br />

Another key variable is accessibility. Access to markets, infrastructure, <strong>and</strong> urban centers has<br />

a large bearing on the opportunities for non-farm employment, the cost of marketing crops, the cost of<br />

obtaining inputs, <strong>and</strong> the availability of information needed to make economic decisions. In this<br />

analysis we use a “hardship factors” calculated by the Vietnamese government to determine the<br />

hardship allowance paid to government staff posted to rural areas. The hardship factor is calculated<br />

for each commune in the country <strong>and</strong> is based on 'natural factors' such as climate <strong>and</strong> altitude, as well<br />

as on accessibility by road, <strong>and</strong> availability of services such as schools, health stations, <strong>and</strong> so on (see<br />

Table 5-1 <strong>and</strong> Figure 5-2).<br />

In the 16 communes where the QSAID Household Survey was carried out, the<br />

hardship factor takes five values: 0.1, 0.3, 0.4, 0.5, <strong>and</strong> 0.7. In order to create categories with at least<br />

50 households each, we combine the third <strong>and</strong> fourth hardship categories to create the accessibility<br />

variable used in the analysis. More specifically, the accessibility category is 1 (low) if the hardship<br />

factor is 0.7, 2 if the hardship factor is 0.5, 3 if it is 0.3 or 0.4, <strong>and</strong> accessibility is 4 (high) if the<br />

hardship factor is 0.1.<br />

5.2 General characteristics<br />

We are interested in household st<strong>and</strong>ards of living for several reasons. First, it is useful to<br />

have a concrete image of the st<strong>and</strong>ard of living of rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. Second,<br />

we would like to see if the livelihood strategies, sources of income, <strong>and</strong> views about the process of<br />

diversification differ between lower <strong>and</strong> higher income households. And third, this information<br />

allows us to compare our results with those of larger surveys with stratified r<strong>and</strong>om samples to verify<br />

the representativeness of our respondents. In this section, we examine four types of data that reflect<br />

the living conditions of rural households: household size <strong>and</strong> composition, housing characteristics,<br />

ownership of assets, <strong>and</strong> perceived income <strong>and</strong> food security.<br />

Page 99


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

5.2.1 Household size <strong>and</strong> composition<br />

With regard to household composition, the average household in our sample has 5.9 people,<br />

including 1.2 children under the age of 10 <strong>and</strong> 0.4 adults over the age of 60. The head of the<br />

household is, on average, 41 years old <strong>and</strong> has 6.1 years of education. As a basis of comparison,<br />

according to the 1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey, among rural households in the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s, the average household had 5.1 members, the average head of household is 44 years old, <strong>and</strong><br />

the average head has 7.4 years of education 2 .<br />

Fourteen ethnic groups were represented among the households in the sample, the most<br />

common ones being H’Mong (25 percent), Tay (24 percent), Kinh (18 percent), <strong>and</strong> Nung (10<br />

percent). About three-quarters of the heads of households speak Vietnamese <strong>and</strong> 62 percent indicate<br />

that they can read Vietnamese. Of the others, some claim to be able to speak or read “a little”<br />

Vietnamese (see Table 5-2).<br />

Dividing our sample into three income terciles 3 , we find that those in the higher-income<br />

category have fewer children, are more educated, <strong>and</strong> are more likely to speak <strong>and</strong> read Vietnamese<br />

(see Appendix D for a description of the method used to divide the households into income groups).<br />

For example, in the lowest income tercile, the heads of household have an average of 4.7 years of<br />

education, compared to 6.0 years in the middle tercile <strong>and</strong> 7.3 years in the highest income tercile. The<br />

household size falls from 7.2 members in the lowest terciles to 4.8 members in the highest tercile.<br />

Ethnicity is also strongly correlated with income. For example, the H’Mong account for over half the<br />

poorest tercile but just 4 percent of the richest tercile. Ethnic Vietnamese households represent just 2<br />

percent of those in the poorest tercile, but 38 percent of the least-poor tercile.<br />

Table 5-2. Household size <strong>and</strong> composition by income category<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

Age 37.6 41.9 43.5 41.0<br />

Education (yrs) 4.7 6.0 7.3 6.1<br />

Household size 7.2 5.5 4.8 5.9<br />

Children (


Figure 5-2. Hardship factor used to calculate hardship allowance for public employees<br />

Source: Ministry of Labor, Invalids, <strong>and</strong> Social Affairs (MOLISA), 2001.<br />

Page 101


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

5.2.2 Housing<br />

The survey also collected information on housing characteristics. About half of the houses<br />

have walls made of wood or bamboo. The remainder is split fairly evenly between those with more<br />

permanent walls made of fired brick or stone (21 percent) <strong>and</strong> those made of earth (22 percent).<br />

About half (56 percent) of the roofs were tiled, while another 26 percent were straw, grass, or thatch.<br />

Finally, about half (49 percent) of the houses had earth floors, followed by concrete or brick (22<br />

percent) <strong>and</strong> wood or bamboo (19 percent). Almost two-thirds (64 percent) have electricity, although<br />

many of the houses were electrified only in the last few years: half of those with electricity received it<br />

within the last three years (see Table 5-3)<br />

As expected, the housing characteristics vary significantly across income groups. The higher<br />

income households are much more likely to have concrete, brick, or stone walls, concrete or tile roofs,<br />

<strong>and</strong> tile, brick, or concrete floors. The poorest rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s are likely to<br />

have wood, bamboo, or earth walls, straw or thatch roofs, <strong>and</strong> earth floors.<br />

Table 5-3. Characteristics of houses by income category<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

(percentage of households)<br />

Concrete 0 1 9 3<br />

Fired brick/stone 7 18 37 21<br />

Unfired brick 1 0 5 2<br />

Earth 22 28 17 22<br />

Wood/bamboo 71 53 31 52<br />

Other 0 0 1 0<br />

Total 100 100 100 100<br />

Walls<br />

Roof<br />

(percentage of households)<br />

Concrete 0 1 18 6<br />

Tile 40 74 55 56<br />

Metal 0 5 5 3<br />

Wood/bamboo 10 2 6 6<br />

Staw/thatch 50 19 10 26<br />

Other 1 0 7 3<br />

Total 100 100 100 100<br />

Floor<br />

(percentage of households)<br />

Marble/tile 1 1 19 7<br />

Concrete/brick 3 23 40 22<br />

Wood/bamboo 23 21 14 19<br />

Earth 73 54 21 49<br />

Other 0 2 7 3<br />

Total 100 100 100 100<br />

5.2.3 Assets<br />

With regard to assets, the survey collected information on ownership of selected consumer<br />

goods (radio, television, bicycle, <strong>and</strong> motorbike or other vehicle) <strong>and</strong> information on access to l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Somewhat more than half the households in the sample (57 percent) owned a working radio. Similar<br />

percentages owned a television (53 percent) <strong>and</strong> a bicycle (56 percent). The percentage owing a<br />

motorbike or other vehicle was 42 percent (see Table 5-4).<br />

Page 102


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Table 5-4. Ownership of radio, television, bicycle <strong>and</strong> vehicle by<br />

income category<br />

Assets<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

Type Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

(percentage of households owning)<br />

Radio 36 61 74 57<br />

Television 11 58 87 53<br />

Bicycle 23 59 84 56<br />

Other vehicle 9 33 84 42<br />

L<strong>and</strong> is probably the most important physical asset controlled by rural households. The<br />

average household in the sample cultivates 1.07 hectares of l<strong>and</strong>, including about 0.31 hectares of<br />

lowl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> 0.76 hectares of upl<strong>and</strong> (see Table 5-5). Of this, 0.18 hectares are irrigated, accounting<br />

for about 57 percent of the lowl<strong>and</strong> area. Very little cultivated l<strong>and</strong> (5 percent) is borrowed or rented<br />

from other farmers or local authorities. Most is “owned” by the household in the sense that they have<br />

long-term leases on l<strong>and</strong>. On average, 0.68 hectares of l<strong>and</strong> are “owned with title,” meaning that the<br />

household has an official l<strong>and</strong>-use certificate, also called a “red-book”. Over three-quarters (78<br />

percent) of the lowl<strong>and</strong> area is covered by l<strong>and</strong>-use certificates, while just half (50 percent) the upl<strong>and</strong><br />

area is. This reflects national trends in that the allocation of l<strong>and</strong>-use certificates for lowl<strong>and</strong> plots is<br />

nearing completion, while that of upl<strong>and</strong> areas is much less advanced.<br />

Somewhat surprisingly, access to l<strong>and</strong> does not differ significantly across income groups<br />

within the sample, although poor households have a smaller share of irrigated l<strong>and</strong> (12 percent)<br />

compared to higher-income households. Accessibility does, however, make a difference. Households<br />

in the more remote villages generally have a similar amount of lowl<strong>and</strong> but more upl<strong>and</strong> area<br />

compared to those in more accessible villages. This is presumably a reflection of the lower<br />

population density <strong>and</strong> lower productivity of l<strong>and</strong> in the remote areas (see Table 5-6).<br />

Table 5-5. Composition of agricultural l<strong>and</strong><br />

Tenure status Lowl<strong>and</strong> Upl<strong>and</strong> Total Irrigated<br />

(area in m2 per household)<br />

Own with title 2,425 3,761 6,186 1,545<br />

Own w/o title 590 3,344 3,935 189<br />

Rent/borrow 77 471 548 23<br />

Total 3,092 7,576 10,668 1,757<br />

Table 5-6. L<strong>and</strong> type by income tercile (m2)<br />

Type of l<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

(area in m2 per household)<br />

Lowl<strong>and</strong> 3,171 3,252 2,792 3,072<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong> 8,739 7,093 6,736 7,527<br />

Total 11,910 10,345 9,528 10,599<br />

Of which:<br />

Irrigated 1,338 1,341 2,562 1,746<br />

With title 5,692 5,642 7,107 6,145<br />

Page 103


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

5.3 Food security <strong>and</strong> income<br />

5.3.1 Perceived level of food security <strong>and</strong> income<br />

How to households perceive their own situation regarding food security <strong>and</strong> income<br />

Respondents were asked “concerning rice <strong>and</strong> other food crops 4 , last year you produced enough food<br />

to feed your household for how many months” Almost 62 percent reported that their own food<br />

production was enough to feed the family for a full 12 months per year. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, 11 percent<br />

reported that it lasted 6 months or less (see). This information may be misleading because it measures<br />

household food self-sufficiency, which is not the same as food security. For example, households<br />

with stable non-farm income, such as school teachers <strong>and</strong> government employees, may not produce<br />

much of their own food but they may still be able to secure enough food.<br />

Table 5-7. Months covered by own food production<br />

Months of Number of Percent of Cumulative<br />

food households households percent<br />

2 4 1 1<br />

3 7 2 4<br />

4 6 2 6<br />

5 3 1 7<br />

6 13 4 11<br />

7 5 2 13<br />

8 13 4 17<br />

9 18 6 23<br />

10 37 13 36<br />

11 6 2 38<br />

12 182 62 100<br />

Total 294 100<br />

An alternative, perhaps better, way to measure of food security is to ask if the household<br />

experienced hunger during the past year <strong>and</strong>, if so, for how many months. Over two-thirds of the<br />

respondents (69 percent) said they had not experienced hunger. Another 10 percent said that they<br />

experienced four or more months of hunger during the year (see Table 5-8) these figures are affected<br />

by different definitions of “hunger”, it seems clear that, although the majority of households are food<br />

secure, it is too soon to say that hunger has been eliminated.<br />

Both these indicators of food security are correlated with our index of household well-being.<br />

For example, the proportion of households with zero months of hunger rises from 47 percent in the<br />

lowest income group to 93 percent in the highest group. Similarly, the percentage of households that<br />

produces 12 months of food supply for itself rises from 42 percent in the low-income group to 79<br />

percent in the high-income category (see Table 5-9).<br />

4<br />

In Vietnam, “food” is generally defined to include rice, maize, sweet potatoes, <strong>and</strong> cassava.<br />

Page 104


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Table 5-8. Number of months experienced hunger by income category<br />

Months of<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

hunger Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

0 45 76 92 69<br />

1 3 2 1 2<br />

2 21 9 4 12<br />

3 13 5 1 7<br />

4 4 2 1 3<br />

5 2 2 0 2<br />

6 8 2 0 4<br />

7 0 1 0 0<br />

8 2 0 0 1<br />

10 1 0 0 0<br />

Total 100. 100 100 100<br />

Table 5-9. Number of months covered by own food production<br />

by income category<br />

Months of<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

food Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

2 3 1 0 1<br />

3 3 2 2 2<br />

4 5 1 0 2<br />

5 2 0 1 1<br />

6 7 5 1 4<br />

7 2 2 1 2<br />

8 8 0 5 4<br />

9 8 8 2 6<br />

10 19 12 6 13<br />

11 2 2 2 2<br />

12 41 66 79 62<br />

Total 100 100 100 100<br />

Although it is not possible to get reliable estimates of income or expenditure in a<br />

questionnaire this size, we did ask households how they would rank their st<strong>and</strong>ard of living compared<br />

to others in the village <strong>and</strong> compared to their own household in 1994. Almost half (48 percent)<br />

described their well-being as “about the same” as those of others in the same village, while similar<br />

numbers described themselves as “better off” (27 percent) <strong>and</strong> “worse off” (24 percent). This selfassessment<br />

was correlated with the estimated income tercile based on household characteristics,<br />

though the correlation is not exact. Sixteen percent of those in the lowest income tercile rated<br />

themselves as better than average, while 8 percent of those in the upper tercile described themselves<br />

as worse than average (see Table 5-10). These results are not necessarily contradictory since the selfassessments<br />

were relative to others in the village, while the income terciles are compared to others in<br />

the sample.<br />

Table 5-10. St<strong>and</strong>ard of living compared to others in village by income tercile<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard of living<br />

compared to others<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

in village Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

Better 17 22 44 27<br />

Average 44 53 48 48<br />

Worse 40 25 8 24<br />

Total 100 100 100 100<br />

Page 105


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

5.3.2 Perceived changes in income<br />

Respondents were also asked to assess their current st<strong>and</strong>ard of living compared to their<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard of living in 1994. Given the rapid economic growth that Vietnam has experienced, it is not<br />

surprising that many households report being better off now. Nonetheless, the margin found in this<br />

survey is quite remarkable: almost 83 percent of the households reported that they were better off than<br />

in 1994. Another 16 percent said they are about the same, <strong>and</strong> just 1 percent (3 households) reported<br />

being worse off (see Table 5-11). Even if we take into account the fact that some of these responses<br />

may be exaggerated, these results suggest that the benefits of economic growth has not been limited to<br />

the larger cities or the more favored rural areas. Rather, it has extended even into relatively remote<br />

parts of the northern mountain region.<br />

Table 5-11. St<strong>and</strong>ard of living compared to 1994<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard of living<br />

compared to 1994 Number Percent<br />

Better 247 83<br />

No change 49 16<br />

Worse 3 1<br />

Total 299 100<br />

The proportion of households reporting higher st<strong>and</strong>ards of living was greater among the<br />

upper income tercile (94 percent) than among those in the lower-income tercile (71percent). These<br />

results do not necessarily imply that the rural elite are gaining more from economic growth because<br />

some of them may not have been “rich” in 1994 5 . Dividing the sample by accessibility gives similar<br />

results. The percentage of household reporting improvement is higher among those in more<br />

accessible villages (89 percent) compared to those in the least accessible villages (79 percent). But it<br />

is worth noting that even in the most inaccessible villages in the sample, over three-quarters of the<br />

households reported rising st<strong>and</strong>ards of living (see Table 5-12).<br />

Table 5-12. St<strong>and</strong>ard of living compared to 1994 by accessibility<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard of living<br />

Accessibility<br />

compared to 1994 Low 2 3 High Total<br />

Better 79 83 82 89 83<br />

No change 21 16 17 9 16<br />

Worse 0 1 1 2 1<br />

Total 100 100 100 100 100<br />

5 This is a problem of sample selection bias <strong>and</strong> can be illustrated with a hypothetical example.<br />

Suppose all households had the same income in 1994 <strong>and</strong> some grew richer <strong>and</strong> some grew poorer at r<strong>and</strong>om.<br />

We would find that the households who are richer in 2002 would report rising income, while the poor would<br />

report declining income, in spite of the fact that all households started out with the same income <strong>and</strong> the changes<br />

in income were r<strong>and</strong>omly allocated.<br />

Page 106


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

5.3.3 Perceived reasons for changes in income<br />

Given the large numbers of rural households that feel that their st<strong>and</strong>ard of living has<br />

improved over the last eight years, an obvious question is what are the main factors behind this<br />

improvement. Households were asked to name up to three factors that were important in contributing<br />

to the change in income since 1994. The questionnaire has nine pre-coded responses, but respondents<br />

were allowed to give other answers as well. Among those households reporting an improved st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

of living, the most common explanation, offered by 64 percent of the respondents, was that their crop<br />

yields had increased (see Table 5-13 <strong>and</strong> Figure 5-3). In addition, 50 percent said that their household<br />

had benefited from increased income from livestock production. And the third most common<br />

response, cited by 38 percent, was that the household grows new crops that are more profitable than<br />

before. Less common responses included more l<strong>and</strong> to cultivate (27 percent), higher cropping<br />

intensity (24 percent), more income from forestry-related activities (19 percent), <strong>and</strong> more income<br />

from non-farm enterprises (11 percent).<br />

The responses differed by income group, however. For example, growing new crops with<br />

higher profits was mentioned by 56 percent of those in the upper income group but only 17 percent of<br />

those in the lower income group. Higher income households were also more likely to cite area<br />

expansion, livestock income, forestry, <strong>and</strong> non-farm enterprise income. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, higher<br />

crop yields were cited by rich <strong>and</strong> poor rural households in similar percentages.<br />

Table 5-13. Reported reasons for improved st<strong>and</strong>ard of living of household by income tercile<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

Total<br />

Reasons for improved living conditions Lower Middle Upper<br />

Increase in l<strong>and</strong> available for farming 17 36 29 27<br />

Increase in cropping intensity 22 24 27 24<br />

Increase in crop yields 62 63 65 64<br />

Grows new crops with higher profits 17 41 56 38<br />

Earns more income from livestock 46 46 56 50<br />

Earns more income from fisheries 0 10 7 6<br />

Earns more income from forestry 10 22 24 19<br />

Earns more income from wages 2 5 7 5<br />

Earns more income from NF enterprises 2 12 19 11<br />

Other 10 15 17 14<br />

Total 189 274 308 257<br />

Note: Percentages sum to more than 100 percent because respondents were allowed<br />

to give up multiple responses.<br />

Page 107


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Figure 5-3. Reported reasons for improved st<strong>and</strong>ard of living of household<br />

Percent of respondents<br />

0% 20% 40% 60% 80%<br />

More farm l<strong>and</strong><br />

Higher cropping intensity<br />

Higher crop yields<br />

New crops with higher profits<br />

More income from livestock<br />

More income from fisheries<br />

More income from forestry<br />

More income from wages<br />

More enterprise income<br />

27%<br />

24%<br />

38%<br />

50%<br />

6%<br />

19%<br />

5%<br />

11%<br />

64%<br />

In order to verify whether the selected households were typical in their sources of income<br />

growth, the survey also asked respondents about the factors behind the income growth of other<br />

households in the village whose st<strong>and</strong>ard of living had improved. The results were quite similar, with<br />

higher yields <strong>and</strong> livestock income each being cited by over 60 percent of the respondents <strong>and</strong><br />

diversification into high-value crops being listed by almost half (see Table 5-14).<br />

Table 5-14. Reported reasons for improved st<strong>and</strong>ard of living of neighbors<br />

Number of Percent of<br />

Reasons for other households improving responses households<br />

Increase in l<strong>and</strong> available for farming 97 32<br />

Increase in cropping intensity 94 31<br />

Increase in crop yields 212 69<br />

Grows new crops with higher profits 142 46<br />

Earns more income from livestock 186 61<br />

Earns more income from fisheries 22 7<br />

Earns more income from forestry 68 22<br />

Earns more income from wages 6 2<br />

Earns more income from NF enterprises 20 7<br />

Other 54 18<br />

Total 901 295<br />

Note: Percentages sum to more than 100 percent because respondents were allowed<br />

to give multiple reasons.<br />

The reasons households gave for their improved st<strong>and</strong>ard of living varied somewhat across<br />

income groups. Yields were mentioned by a larger share of those in the bottom tercile (93 percent)<br />

compared to the top tercile (69 percent). The reverse pattern was found in the case of new high-value<br />

crops <strong>and</strong> income from non-farm enterprises. Among those in the low-income tercile, just 27 percent<br />

cited growing new high-value crops as a major factor in their improved st<strong>and</strong>ard of living compared<br />

to 61 percent of those in the high-income tercile. Similarly, just 4 percent of those in the bottom<br />

Page 108


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

income group mentioned non-farm enterprise income, compared to 22 percent in the top income<br />

group. Thus, it appears that the poorest rural households are more likely to gain from yield increases<br />

<strong>and</strong> livestock income, while somewhat higher-income rural households gain from a combination of<br />

higher yields, more profitable crops, <strong>and</strong> livestock income.<br />

The large number of households citing higher yields as an important factor in rising rural<br />

incomes is consistent with the results of the analysis of household surveys in Chapter 3, in which<br />

yield growth was the largest factor behind crop income growth. In the context of Vietnam, it is likely<br />

that yields showed a noticeable rise as a result of improvements in irrigation infrastructure, water<br />

management, <strong>and</strong> production methods. All three of these factors may be linked to the distribution of<br />

“red book” l<strong>and</strong>-use certificates. The 1993 L<strong>and</strong> Law called for the distribution of l<strong>and</strong>-use<br />

certificates as a way of formalizing the de facto allocation of cooperative farm l<strong>and</strong> among member<br />

households. This gave rural households greater confidence that the reforms would not be reversed<br />

<strong>and</strong> that the returns to farm-level investments would be accrue to the household.<br />

These results indicate that income diversification has played a role in increasing rural incomes<br />

in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s over the last eight years. Agricultural diversification (from crops into<br />

livestock) was the second most common explanation given for rising incomes <strong>and</strong> crop diversification<br />

(from low-value to high-value crops) was the third most common response. <strong>Diversification</strong> into<br />

forestry, non-farm enterprises, <strong>and</strong> fisheries are also cited, though less often.<br />

What about households whose st<strong>and</strong>ard of living has declined since 1994 As mentioned<br />

above, only three households in the sample reported being worse off, so we cannot draw any useful<br />

information from their experience. All respondents were also asked, however, about others in the<br />

village whose well-being had declined <strong>and</strong> what the reasons behind that decline were. Here, there was<br />

much less consensus. The most common responses were less l<strong>and</strong> for cultivation (28 percent), many<br />

children (18 percent), that they were lazy (11 percent), <strong>and</strong> that they lack capital for productive<br />

investment (11 percent). Other reasons given included lack of production knowledge, illness, reduced<br />

income from livestock, <strong>and</strong> lack of labor.<br />

The results presented here suggest that rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s are quite<br />

poor by almost any definition of the word. At the same time, a large majority of them report that their<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard of living has increased since 1994, <strong>and</strong> these gains are reported in remote villages as well as<br />

in more accessible ones. Finally, income diversification (along with higher crop yields) are credited<br />

by rural households as being one of the main driving forces behind this increase in income. The next<br />

section examines the income-generating activities of rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong><br />

how they have changed over the recent past.<br />

Page 109


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

5.4 Sources of income<br />

The previous section examined overall st<strong>and</strong>ard of living. This section focuses on the<br />

livelihood strategies of rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. In particular, we are interested in<br />

the sources of income earned by the households <strong>and</strong> how these patterns have changed over the last<br />

eight years.<br />

5.4.1 Current income sources<br />

With regard to current income, the survey asked households to rank their three most important<br />

sources of income <strong>and</strong> list any others. The responses were coded into 39 possible activities, including<br />

16 crop categories, 6 livestock categories, 7 forestry <strong>and</strong> fishing categories, <strong>and</strong> 10 types of nonagricultural<br />

income.<br />

Rice continues to be the most important source of income in spite of gradual diversification<br />

into other crops <strong>and</strong> non-crop activities. Over half (55 percent) of the households in the sample cited<br />

rice production as their most important source of income. Maize is a distant second, identified by 13<br />

percent of the households as the most important source. Litchi, pigs, <strong>and</strong> tea are the most important<br />

sources of income for smaller numbers of rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s (see Table 5-15).<br />

The results are fairly similar if we examine the top three sources of income: rice, maize, <strong>and</strong><br />

pigs are the most commonly mentioned income sources, followed by cassava <strong>and</strong> litchi. Overall, 91<br />

percent of the households report some income from rice production. Large proportions of households<br />

are also involved in pig production (86 percent), maize cultivation (76 percent), <strong>and</strong> poultry<br />

production (73 percent). No other activity is reported by over half of the respondents, although<br />

cassava <strong>and</strong> buffalo come close (48 percent <strong>and</strong> 44 percent, respectively).<br />

Among non-farm activities, the most common was non-agricultural wage employment,<br />

followed by trading, agricultural processing, <strong>and</strong> agricultural wage employment. These would include<br />

teachers, retail vendors, rice millers, <strong>and</strong> day laborers. None was particularly common, partly because<br />

the sample was designed to focus on farmers.<br />

There is some variation in income sources across income categories, but the differences are<br />

surprisingly small. Households in the poorest income group are more likely to report income from<br />

maize, cassava, cattle raising, <strong>and</strong> agricultural wages, but they are less likely to earn money from fruit<br />

production, trading, processing, <strong>and</strong> remittances. These differences can be explained by the larger<br />

share of upl<strong>and</strong> farm area, the smaller irrigated area, <strong>and</strong> the investment costs associated with treecrop<br />

production <strong>and</strong> non-farm enterprises.<br />

Page 110


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Table 5-15. Main source of income <strong>and</strong> top three sources of income<br />

Sources Main source Top three sources<br />

of income of income of income<br />

(percent of households citing)<br />

Rice 55 91<br />

Maize 13 76<br />

Sweet potato 0 14<br />

Potato 0 4<br />

Cassava 1 48<br />

Beans 0 23<br />

Other legumes 0 9<br />

Vegetables 0 14<br />

Litchi 9 17<br />

Longan 0 7<br />

Other fruit 3 27<br />

Tea 4 20<br />

Sugarcane 0 1<br />

Pepper 0 0<br />

Other ind. crops 2 7<br />

Opium 0 0<br />

Beef cattle 3 21<br />

Dairy cattle 0 2<br />

Buffalo 1 44<br />

Pigs 5 86<br />

Poultry 0 73<br />

Other animals 0 9<br />

Fishes 0 13<br />

Fisheries 0 3<br />

Fire wood 0 15<br />

Other wood 0 4<br />

Medicinal plants 0 5<br />

Wildlife 0 0<br />

Other forest prod 1 14<br />

Mining 0 0<br />

Ag trading 1 2<br />

Other trading 2 6<br />

Ag processing 0 4<br />

Other business 1 5<br />

Ag wages 1 8<br />

Non-ag wages 2 10<br />

Remittances 3 17<br />

Family aid 0 2<br />

Government aid 0 23<br />

As discussed earlier, diversification can be defined in terms of the number of economic<br />

activities or in terms of the importance of non-food <strong>and</strong> non-agricultural activities in the family<br />

budget. Overall, the average household in the sample reported income from 6.8 of the 36 income<br />

generating activities 6 (see Table 5-16). Virtually all households have some non-food income (99<br />

percent) <strong>and</strong> some non-crop income (98 percent), <strong>and</strong> 31 percent have non-agricultural income. Is<br />

diversification greater among higher income households The answer is yes, but not by much.<br />

Households in the lowest tercile have 6.4 sources of income on average, while those in the highest<br />

tercile have 7.2. The number of households having non-agricultural income is also greater among<br />

those in the highest tercile (36 percent) compared to the lowest tercile (28 percent).<br />

6 For these calculations, we exclude the three types of transfer income: remittances, family aid, <strong>and</strong><br />

government aid.<br />

Page 111


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Table 5-16. Measures of income diversification by income category<br />

Number of ---- Percentage of households with ------<br />

<strong>Income</strong> income Non-food Non-crop Non-agricultural<br />

tercile sources income income income<br />

Lower 6.45 99 98 27<br />

Middle 6.80 99 97 27<br />

Upper 7.17 100 99 37<br />

Total 6.80 .99 98 31<br />

5.4.2 Changes in income sources over time<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> can also be defined as a process that occurs over time. Thus, we are interested<br />

in how income sources have changed over time. The respondents were asked which of their current<br />

income sources were started within the last eight years (since 1994) <strong>and</strong> which ones did they have in<br />

1994 but have since given up. An impressive 83 percent of the respondents had adopted at least one<br />

new source of income since 1994. Furthermore, this experimentation was not limited to the rural rich:<br />

at least 80 percent of each income tercile reported adopting a new crop or income-earning activity.<br />

The most commonly cited new income sources were tea (14 percent of the households), litchi (14<br />

percent), other fruit (13 percent), <strong>and</strong> other industrial crops (10 percent) (see Table 5-17).<br />

Fewer households reported ab<strong>and</strong>oning an income source. The most commonly mentioned<br />

crops that were no longer grown by the household were cassava (14 percent of the households), beans<br />

(4 percent), <strong>and</strong> opium 7 (4 percent).<br />

We can reconstruct the types of income earned by our sample households in 1994 by<br />

combining information on current income sources, new sources, <strong>and</strong> ab<strong>and</strong>oned sources. Comparing<br />

the income sources in 1994 <strong>and</strong> 2002, it is clear that there has been some diversification away from<br />

starchy staples such as cassava <strong>and</strong> toward tea, fruit, livestock, <strong>and</strong> non-farm activities. Although<br />

non-farm activities are still not widespread, the percentage of households in our sample earning this<br />

type of income has increased from 17 percent to 31 percent. This contrasts with the VLSS results, in<br />

which the proportion of households with non-farm enterprise income has fallen in most regions of<br />

Vietnam.<br />

7 Since it is illegal to grow opium, we must interpret these results with caution. It is likely that farmers<br />

would deny growing it, though it is not clear whether they would under-report or over-report having given up<br />

opium cultivation.<br />

Page 112


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Table 5-17. New <strong>and</strong> ab<strong>and</strong>oned sources of income<br />

New sources of income Sources of income<br />

Sources of income started since 1994 given up since 1994<br />

(percentage of households reporting)<br />

Rice 6 0<br />

Maize 5 2<br />

Sweet potato 0 1<br />

Cassava 3 14<br />

Beans 5 4<br />

Other legumes 2 1<br />

Vegetables 1 0<br />

Litchi 14 0<br />

Longan 3 0<br />

Other fruit 13 1<br />

Tea 14 1<br />

Sugarcane 1 1<br />

Pepper 0 1<br />

Other ind. crops 10 3<br />

Opium 0 4<br />

Beef cattle 6 2<br />

Dairy cattle 0 0<br />

Buffalo 7 2<br />

Pigs 8 1<br />

Poultry 3 0<br />

Other animals 2 0<br />

Fishes 4 1<br />

Fisheries 0 0<br />

Fire wood 1 3<br />

Other wood 2 2<br />

Medicinal plants 4 0<br />

Wildlife 0 2<br />

Other forest prod 7 3<br />

Mining 0 2<br />

Ag trading 1 1<br />

Other trading 3 1<br />

Ag processing 3 0<br />

Other business 4 0<br />

Ag wages 3 1<br />

Non-ag wages 5 1<br />

Remittances 6 2<br />

Family aid 0 0<br />

Government aid 8 0<br />

One exception to the trend of diversification away from staple food crops is the increasing<br />

share of households growing rice (from 84 to 90 percent). This may reflect investments in irrigation<br />

that have made expansion of rice area possible. In addition, it may reflect the expansion of rice<br />

exports. In the early 1990s, a government imposed rice export quota kept exports below 2 million<br />

tons. Since 1997, the government has gradually relaxed the quota allowing exports to rise to about 4<br />

million tons, though low international prices have since partially reversed this trend.<br />

Page 113


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Table 5-18. Trend of diversification in 1994 <strong>and</strong> 2002<br />

Source <strong>Income</strong> sources <strong>Income</strong> sources<br />

in 1994 in 2002<br />

(percent of households reporting)<br />

Rice 84 90<br />

Maize 72 75<br />

Sweet potato 15 14<br />

Potato 2 4<br />

Cassava 58 48<br />

Beans 22 23<br />

Other legumes 8 9<br />

Vegetables 13 14<br />

Litchi 4 17<br />

Longan 6 7<br />

Other fruit 15 27<br />

Tea 8 20<br />

Sugarcane 1 1<br />

Pepper 1 0<br />

Other ind. crops 5 7<br />

Opium 4 0<br />

Beef cattle 16 21<br />

Dairy cattle 2 2<br />

Buffalo 38 44<br />

Pigs 78 86<br />

Poultry 71 73<br />

Other animals 7 9<br />

Fishes 10 13<br />

Fisheries 3 3<br />

Fire wood 16 15<br />

Other wood 4 4<br />

Medicinal plants 2 5<br />

Wildlife 2 0<br />

Other forest prod 10 14<br />

Mining 2 0<br />

Ag trading 1 2<br />

Other trading 4 6<br />

Ag processing 1 4<br />

Other business 1 5<br />

Ag wages 6 8<br />

Non-ag wages 6 10<br />

Total 596 680<br />

Other definitions of diversification focus on the number of income sources. By this definition<br />

as well, rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s have diversified their income sources somewhat<br />

since 1994. Of the 36 income sources listed, the average number of income sources per household<br />

has increased from 5.9 to 6.8. In addition, the percentage of households earning non-agricultural<br />

income has increased from 17 percent to 31 percent over the eight year period. Furthermore, these<br />

trends are found in poor rural households as well as those somewhat better off.<br />

<strong>Income</strong> diversification does not have to involve ab<strong>and</strong>oning some income sources <strong>and</strong><br />

adopting new ones, however. It may mean changing the relative importance of income-generating<br />

activities. To capture this type of change, the QSAID Household Survey asked which activities have<br />

become more <strong>and</strong> less important since 1994. When asked about activities whose importance has<br />

increased, respondents cited rice (mentioned by 61 percent of the households), maize (44 percent),<br />

<strong>and</strong> pigs (41 percent). When asked about activities that have become less important to the household,<br />

the most common responses were cassava (45 percent of the respondents), poultry (22 percent), <strong>and</strong><br />

firewood (12 percent) (see Table 5-19, Figure 5-4, <strong>and</strong> Figure 5-5).<br />

Page 114


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Table 5-19. Sources becoming more <strong>and</strong> less important over time in village<br />

<strong>Income</strong> source that are becoming:<br />

more important less important<br />

(percent of households reporting)<br />

Rice 61 5<br />

Maize 44 6<br />

Sweet potato 0 5<br />

Cassava 6 45<br />

Beans 6 4<br />

Other legumes 1 2<br />

Vegetables 0 0<br />

Litchi 12 0<br />

Longan 1 2<br />

Other fruit 11 8<br />

Tea 17 2<br />

Sugarcane 1 1<br />

Pepper 0 0<br />

Other ind. crops 8 5<br />

Opium 0 3<br />

Beef cattle 10 3<br />

Dairy cattle 0 0<br />

Buffalo 18 6<br />

Pigs 41 8<br />

Poultry 7 22<br />

Other animals 1 0<br />

Fishes 0 3<br />

Fisheries 0 1<br />

Firewood 1 12<br />

Other wood 1 4<br />

Medicinal plants 4 1<br />

Wildlife 0 0<br />

Other forest prod 7 6<br />

Mining 0 2<br />

Ag trading 3 0<br />

Other trading 3 0<br />

Ag processing 1 0<br />

Other business 0 1<br />

Ag wages 3 3<br />

Non-ag wages 3 2<br />

Remittances 0 1<br />

Government aid 10 0<br />

Figure 5-4. Sources of income becoming more important over time<br />

% of households<br />

0% 20% 40% 60% 80%<br />

Rice<br />

Maize<br />

Pigs<br />

Buffalo<br />

Tea<br />

Litchi<br />

Page 115


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Figure 5-5. Sources of income becoming less important over time<br />

% of households<br />

0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50%<br />

Cassava<br />

Poultry<br />

Firewood<br />

Pigs<br />

Other forest products<br />

Maize<br />

Similar questions were asked regarding changes in the importance of different income sources<br />

among other households in the same village. The responses were quite similar, though the<br />

percentages were naturally higher <strong>and</strong> the range of activities list was wider. For example, increased<br />

importance of litchi, tea, beef cattle, buffalo, <strong>and</strong> other fruit are each mentioned by at least 10 percent<br />

of the sample.<br />

The results presented in this section indicate that rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

have been involved in gradual income diversification over the last eight years. This is true whether<br />

we define diversification in terms of the number of activities, the proportion of households growing<br />

fruit <strong>and</strong> industrial crops, or the proportion involved in non-farm activities. Furthermore, income<br />

diversification is not limited to the rural elite or those in accessible villages near roads <strong>and</strong> cities.<br />

The next section explores in more detail the process of adopting new crops <strong>and</strong> activities.<br />

5.5 Experiences with diversification<br />

The results in the previous section suggest that rural households are trying new crops, but we<br />

do not know what motivates them to do so, whether they have experienced any failures in their<br />

experimentation, what they think are the main constraints to income diversification. These are the<br />

questions that will be addressed in this section.<br />

5.5.1 Successful experiences with diversification<br />

Overall, 56 percent of the households in the sample report that they have successfully<br />

introduced a new crop since 1994, where success is defined in terms of the decision to continue<br />

Page 116


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

growing the crop. The rate of successful adoption is higher among those in the upper income tercile<br />

(65 percent) than in the lower tercile (44 percent), but successful introduction of new crops is<br />

occurring even among the poorest rural households. The rate is even more strongly correlated with<br />

accessibility. The proportion of households successful introducing a new crop rises steadily from 44<br />

percent in the remote villages to 82 percent in the villages with good market access.<br />

Table 5-20. Respondents successfully trying new crops by income tercile<br />

Have tried new crops<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

that succeeded Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

Yes 44 60 63 56<br />

No 56 40 37 44<br />

Total 100 100 100 100<br />

Table 5-21. Respondents successfully trying new crops by accessibility<br />

Have tried new crops<br />

Accessibility<br />

that succeeded Low 2 3 High Total<br />

Yes 44 45 58 82 56<br />

No 56 55 42 18 44<br />

Total 100 100 100 100 100<br />

Table 5-22. Crops listed as most successful new crops<br />

by respondents<br />

Number of Percent of<br />

respondents respondents<br />

Successful new crop<br />

Rice (new variety) 12 7<br />

Maize (new variety) 8 5<br />

Taro 3 2<br />

Soybean 2 1<br />

Litchi 31 18<br />

Longan 1 1<br />

Custard-apple 2 1<br />

Plum 6 4<br />

Orange 1 1<br />

Sapodilla 5 3<br />

Watermelon 1 1<br />

Fruit (various) 4 2<br />

Garlic 1 1<br />

Anise 14 8<br />

Cinamon 4 2<br />

Dia Lien (medicinal) 1 1<br />

Sa moc (medicinal) 4 2<br />

Tea 46 27<br />

Coffee 6 4<br />

Sugarcane 3 2<br />

Palm tree 1 1<br />

Pine 11 7<br />

Bamboo 1 1<br />

Bodhi tree 1 1<br />

Total 169 100<br />

The most commonly cited crops that were successfully adopted are tea, litchi, anise, <strong>and</strong> new<br />

varieties of rice. Tea was mentioned by households in all income terciles with equal frequency, while<br />

litchi was more frequently mentioned by those in the upper-income tercile.<br />

In 42 cases, the new crop was suggested or encouraged by an extension agent or local<br />

authorities. In most cases (54 percent), the response was “other”. After examining the un-coded<br />

responses in the questionnaires, it appears that most of these (37 percent of all respondents) refer to<br />

Page 117


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

cases in which the farmer got the idea of trying the new crop from another farmer. It is interesting to<br />

note that private traders <strong>and</strong> state enterprises played almost no role in introducing new crops to<br />

farmers.<br />

Table 5-23. Person that encouraged new crop that was<br />

successful<br />

Person or<br />

institution Number Percent<br />

Extension agent 42 25<br />

Local authorities 29 17<br />

State enterprise 6 4<br />

Other 91 54<br />

Total 168 100<br />

In cases in which someone was responsible for introducing the crop <strong>and</strong>/or encouraging the<br />

farmer to grow it, we asked what types of assistance or incentive were provided. In three-quarters of<br />

the cases, the farmer was given some information about how to produce the crop <strong>and</strong> in about half the<br />

cases (55 percent) the farmer was sold inputs (see Table 5-24). The farmer received inputs free or on<br />

credit in less than one-third of the cases, though the proportion was about half when the farmer was<br />

motivated by an extension agent. No more than 10 percent of the new adopters received marketing<br />

information or a marketing contract. Thus, it appears that in the majority of cases, the farmer adopts<br />

the new crop with no more assistance than information on how to grow it.<br />

Table 5-24. Types of assistance given to farmers<br />

Type of assistance Number Percent<br />

Show how to grow 90 75<br />

Provided inputs for sale 63 56<br />

Provided inputs free on credit 37 32<br />

Marketing information 9 8<br />

Marketing agreement 11 10<br />

5.5.2 Unsuccessful experiences with diversification<br />

Not all experiments succeed. Roughly one-quarter of the respondents (26 percent) said that<br />

they had had an unsuccessful experience with a new crop, where failure is defined in terms of the<br />

farmer’s decision to discontinue growing it. The proportion of household reporting failed<br />

experiments was higher among households in the upper income tercile. The ratio of successes-tofailures<br />

is lower among poor households, <strong>and</strong>, perhaps for that reason, poor households are less likely<br />

to report either failures or successes.<br />

Table 5-25. Respondents growing new crop unsuccessfully by income tercile<br />

Have tried new crops<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

that failed Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

Yes 20 25 34 26<br />

No 80 75 66 74<br />

Total 100 100 100 100<br />

Page 118


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Respondents were asked to name the crop that they tried to adopt <strong>and</strong> then gave up, or, if<br />

there were more than one, the crop that was the least profitable. Plum <strong>and</strong> apricot were mentioned<br />

most frequently, each cited by 13 percent of those who had an unsuccessful experience.<br />

Table 5-26. Crops listed as least successful new crops by respondents<br />

Number of Percent of<br />

Crop<br />

respondents respondents<br />

Rice (new variety) 3 4<br />

Maize (new variety) 1 1<br />

Cassava 9 11<br />

Potato 1 1<br />

Soybean 3 4<br />

Litchi 3 4<br />

Longan 6 8<br />

Plum 10 13<br />

Orange 5 6<br />

Sapodilla 3 4<br />

Apricot 10 13<br />

Jack fruit 1 1<br />

Breadfruit 1 1<br />

Grapefruit 1 1<br />

Fruit (various) 2 3<br />

Dia Lien (medicinal) 4 5<br />

Tea 2 3<br />

Coffee 5 6<br />

Sugarcane 3 4<br />

Coconut 2 3<br />

Mulberry 1 1<br />

Bamboo 1 1<br />

Betel 1 1<br />

Sticklac (resin) 2 3<br />

Total 80 100<br />

The types of people who encouraged the farmer to grow the unsuccessful crops had roughly<br />

the same composition as the people who encourage the farmer to grow successful crops: 40 percent<br />

extension agents <strong>and</strong> local authorities <strong>and</strong> 58 percent “other” 9 . One difference between successful<br />

<strong>and</strong> unsuccessful cases is that the proportion of farmers being told how to grow the crop was greater<br />

in the successful cases (80 percent) than in the unsuccessful cases (53 percent).<br />

Table 5-27. Person that encouraged new crop that was<br />

not successful<br />

Person or<br />

institution Number Percent<br />

Extension agent 11 18<br />

Local authorities 14 23<br />

State enterprise 1 2<br />

Other 36 58<br />

Total 62 100<br />

5.5.3 Perceptions regarding diversification<br />

In addition to questions about their experience with diversification, the survey asked<br />

respondents about their views regarding the potential for different types of income diversification to<br />

improve their income <strong>and</strong> whether it could raise the income of poor households in their village. Less<br />

9 It is worth noting that the ratio of successes-to-failures is higher for extension agents than it is for<br />

local authorities.<br />

Page 119


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

than half (42 percent) believe that they could increase their income by growing different crops,<br />

though households in the upper tercile were somewhat more optimistic (51 percent) than those in the<br />

lower tercile (36 percent) (see Table 5-28). Those that answered “yes” were asked which crops (up<br />

to three) would increase their income. A wide range of crops were mentioned by the respondents, but<br />

the most commonly mentioned ones were litchi, longan, sapodilla, mango, anise, tea, <strong>and</strong> bamboo.<br />

These seven crops accounted for about two-thirds of the responses given. (see Table 5-29).<br />

Table 5-28. Perception of ability to earn more money from crop diversification<br />

by income tercile<br />

Could earn more with<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

different crops Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

(percentage of respondents)<br />

Yes 36 42 51 131<br />

No 64 58 49 173<br />

Total 100 100 100 304<br />

Table 5-29. Crops perceived as profitable<br />

Number of Percent of<br />

Crop<br />

respondents respondents<br />

Longan 24 11<br />

Bamboo 22 10<br />

Litchi 20 9<br />

Fruit (various) 19 9<br />

Sapodilla 19 9<br />

Tea 18 8<br />

Mango 15 7<br />

Anise 10 5<br />

Sa moc (medicinal) 7 3<br />

Plum 7 3<br />

Custard-apple 6 3<br />

Orange 6 3<br />

Soybean 5 2<br />

Pear 5 2<br />

Other 30 9<br />

Total 214 100<br />

If these crops would help them increase their income, the obvious question is why they are<br />

not growing them now. The most common response was lack of capital (21 percent), while other<br />

responses include lack of seeds, lack of l<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> lack of information about production methods.<br />

Some respondents said that market <strong>and</strong> transport are the main constraints for them.<br />

One-third of the households felt that they could increase their income by getting involved in<br />

non-crop activities. Those that answered “yes” were asked which activities would be more<br />

profitable. Over half (57 percent) mentioned some type of livestock production, mainly cattle <strong>and</strong><br />

buffalo raising. Another 18 percent cited non-farm businesses, with small numbers listing processing,<br />

hired labor, motorbike repair, <strong>and</strong> transportation, among others. What are the constraints that prevent<br />

them from engaging in these non-crop activities Over half cited lack of capital as the main<br />

constraint. Others mentioned lack of labor, animal diseases, lack of seeds/seedlings, lack of pasture,<br />

small children, <strong>and</strong> lack of information.<br />

Page 120


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Table 5-30. Perception of ability to earn more money from non-crop activities<br />

by income tercile<br />

Could earn more with<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

non-crop activities Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

Yes 33 26 41 33<br />

No 67 74 59 67<br />

Total 100 100 100 100<br />

The survey also included some questions to address more directly the problems of the poor<br />

<strong>and</strong> whether income diversification would help alleviate poverty. We started with a very general<br />

question about the main causes of poverty in their village. The most common reason given (30<br />

percent of the respondents) was lack of l<strong>and</strong>. Other common responses were the low level of<br />

knowledge or education (16 percent), large numbers of children (11 percent), lack of capital (9<br />

percent), <strong>and</strong> laziness (8 percent). Poor health, lack of labor, infertile soils, <strong>and</strong> drug addiction were<br />

also mentioned as causes of poverty. These responses mirror those discussed earlier regarding the<br />

reasons for the deterioration in st<strong>and</strong>ards of living of some households (see Figure 5-6).<br />

Figure 5-6. Perceptions of main causes of poverty<br />

% of responses<br />

0% 10% 20% 30% 40%<br />

Lack of l<strong>and</strong><br />

Low education<br />

Many children<br />

Lack of capital<br />

Laziness<br />

The survey also asked questions about the potential for different types of diversification to<br />

benefit the poor. About half (52 percent) said that growing different crops would help the poor<br />

increase their incomes, <strong>and</strong> close to three-quarters (72 percent) agreed that raising fish or livestock<br />

would help the poor, but just 18 percent said that small businesses or wage income would assist the<br />

poor raise their incomes.<br />

The constraints that prevent the poor from getting involved in new activities are quite similar.<br />

In the case of growing more profitable crops, the main constraints are said to be lack of capital (38<br />

Page 121


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

percent), lack of l<strong>and</strong> (22 percent), <strong>and</strong> lack of information (19 percent). The obstacles faced by the<br />

poor in livestock <strong>and</strong> fish production are similar but in different proportions: 79 percent cite the lack<br />

of capital <strong>and</strong> 14 percent said lack of pasture. And in the case of non-farm activities, lack of capital<br />

was again given as the main constraint (38 percent).<br />

There is little doubt that lack of capital is the most common response to questions about<br />

constraints to diversification. It is important, however, to interpret these results with caution for two<br />

reasons. First, credit programs managed by the government <strong>and</strong> by non-governmental organizations<br />

are often heavily subsidized either through below-market interest rates or through easy forgiveness of<br />

loans. From the responses, it is not clear whether the respondents are stating their need for credit (at<br />

market interest rates) or their interest in receiving subsidies through a credit program. Second,<br />

although the research purposes of the survey were explained to every respondent, some respondents<br />

may feel that reporting a problem of credit will increase their chances of receiving credit in the future,<br />

thus biasing their responses.<br />

Finally, the survey asked whether it was more difficult for ethnic minorities or women to try<br />

new crops or activities. Ethnic minorities may face several barriers to diversification: 1) language<br />

differences may make it difficult for them to obtain technical <strong>and</strong> market information on new crops;<br />

2) lower levels of education may interfere with their ability to make use of technical or marketing<br />

information, 3) cultural differences may make it harder for them to find a buyer that they trust or that<br />

trust them; <strong>and</strong> 4) it may be more difficult for them to apply for or obtain credit. Women may face<br />

similar barriers, as well as the fact that they usually do not have l<strong>and</strong> titles or other forms of collateral<br />

for credit.<br />

In light of these constraints, it is somewhat surprisingly that only 21 percent of the<br />

respondents felt that it was more difficult for women to diversify. To check whether we were simply<br />

picking up the views of men, we separated the answers according to the gender of the respondent.<br />

Among female respondents, the proportion that believed women faced additional difficulties was 20<br />

percent (see Table 5-31).<br />

Table 5-31. Opinion on difficulty of women to try new crops<br />

Harder for women to Gender of respondent<br />

diversify Male Female Total<br />

Yes 21 20 21<br />

No 79 80 79<br />

Total 100 100 100<br />

With regard to ethnicity, less than one-quarter (24 percent) of the respondents said that ethnic<br />

minorities faced additional constraints in diversification. Again, dividing the sample into two groups,<br />

the percentage was 26 percent among ethnic minorities <strong>and</strong> 14 percent among others 10 . Thus, ethnic<br />

10 This category includes the Kinh (ethnic Vietnamese) <strong>and</strong> Hoa (ethnic Chinese), following the<br />

convention used in Vietnam.<br />

Page 122


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

minorities are more likely to say that they face additional constraints than others, but even among<br />

ethnic minorities barely one quarter believe those additional constraints exist (see Table 5-32).<br />

Table 5-32. Opinion on difficulty of ethnic minorities to try new crops<br />

Harder for some ethnic Ethnicity of respondent<br />

groups to diversify Kinh/Hoa Other Total<br />

Yes 14 26 24<br />

No 86 74 76<br />

Total 100 100 100<br />

5.6 Role of traders <strong>and</strong> processors<br />

Traders <strong>and</strong> processors are normally the link between farmers <strong>and</strong> markets. As such they<br />

transmit market signals to the farmer, either implicitly through the prices they are willing to pay for<br />

different commodities, or explicitly by passing on market information to the farmer. Since traders<br />

succeed or fail based on their knowledge of the market, they are potentially a useful source of<br />

information about market conditions in general <strong>and</strong> about opportunities to grow new crops in<br />

particular. Furthermore, because traders <strong>and</strong> processors are often larger <strong>and</strong> more liquid enterprises<br />

than farm households, they are a potential source of credit. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, traders are often seen<br />

as exploitative middle-men, taking advantage of the isolation <strong>and</strong> ignorance of farmers to pay them<br />

less than a “fair” price. To the extent that farmers distrust traders or see the market as inherently<br />

unstable, they will be reluctant to diversify into higher-value commercial crops. This section explores<br />

the role of traders <strong>and</strong> processors in marketing the output of farmers in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

Almost all households in the sample (92 percent) sell at least some of their agricultural<br />

production (including crops, livestock, forestry, <strong>and</strong> fisheries). The proportion of farmers selling is<br />

higher among better-off households, but even among the poorest third of rural households, 80 percent<br />

sell some of their output. Similarly, the percentage is higher among those with good market access,<br />

but even among those living in the most inaccessible villages, 82 percent have agricultural sales.<br />

The respondents were asked to name three most important commodities they sell. The most<br />

frequently mentioned commodity was pig, sold by at least 63 percent of all households in the sample.<br />

Maize <strong>and</strong> rice are sold by 22 <strong>and</strong> 22 percent of the respondents, respectively, followed by poultry,<br />

litchi, <strong>and</strong> tea. Rice <strong>and</strong> poultry are more often cited by poor households, while fruit <strong>and</strong> tea are<br />

much more common among households in the upper income tercile.<br />

The buyer is usually a private traders. Traders account for 78 percent of the sales transactions<br />

recorded in the survey. Consumers <strong>and</strong> private processors are a in a distant second <strong>and</strong> third place,<br />

representing less than 10 percent of the sales transactions each. State enterprises <strong>and</strong> state processors<br />

together account for just 4 percent of the farm-level buyers, although they may receive the<br />

commodities further along the supply chain. Low-income households <strong>and</strong> those in remote locations<br />

are somewhat more likely to sell to consumers than other households, but private traders still account<br />

for the bulk of their sales.<br />

Page 123


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

The buyer almost never provides any assistance to the farmer in terms of production<br />

information, inputs, credit, or marketing contract. Less than 1 percent of the sales transactions<br />

involved any type of assistance from the buyer. In other words, almost all the sales transactions were<br />

on the spot market, regardless of the income or location of the farmer <strong>and</strong> regardless of the type of<br />

buyer.<br />

Table 5-33. Type of buyer of crops by accessibility<br />

Type of buyer<br />

Accessibility<br />

Low 2 3 High Total<br />

(number of respondents)<br />

Private trader 88 137 133 120 478<br />

State enterprise 0 3 7 0 10<br />

Private processor 6 5 8 10 29<br />

State processor 0 2 11 0 13<br />

Consumers 29 9 11 3 52<br />

Other 6 9 10 2 27<br />

Total 129 165 180 135 609<br />

In order to assess the level of competition in agricultural markets, we asked how many buyers<br />

are there to choose from in the same location where the sales transaction was made. For over half the<br />

transactions (58 percent), there were five or more buyers (see Table 5-34). In 6 percent of the cases,<br />

there was just one buyer <strong>and</strong> in 19 percent the respondent did not know. Even among poor<br />

households <strong>and</strong> those in remote villages, it is rare that sales take place in a context of just one buyer.<br />

The percentage of “don’t know” responses is significantly higher among poor <strong>and</strong> isolated farmers,<br />

but these appear to correspond to sales to consumers, where the question is not really applicable.<br />

Table 5-34. Number of buyers for each crop by accessibility category<br />

Accessibility<br />

Number of buyers Low 2 3 High Total<br />

(number of respondents)<br />

More than 10 38 47 37 76 198<br />

5-10 buyers 17 37 51 34 139<br />

2-5 buyers 21 18 43 16 98<br />

Just 1 buyer 4 6 25 1 36<br />

Don't know 45 41 16 6 108<br />

Total 125 149 172 133 579<br />

When asked the reason that this buyer was selected, almost 73 percent of the responses were<br />

that he or she offered the best price. Concerns that previous debts or personal relationships would<br />

obligate a farmer to sell to one buyer appear to be unfounded on the whole. In fact, not only is debt<br />

not a factor in the choice of buyer, but it is very rare for a farm household to owe money to a buyer.<br />

Just 2 percent of the respondents reported this type of debt. Poor households <strong>and</strong> those in remote<br />

villages are somewhat more likely to cite trust/personal relationship, but “best price” is still the most<br />

common reason, accounting for at least 60 percent of all sales transactions.<br />

Page 124


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Table 5-35. Reason for selling crops to current buyer<br />

Accessibility<br />

Reason Low 2 3 High Total<br />

(number of respondents)<br />

Only one 4 6 19 0 29<br />

Offers assistance 0 1 2 0 3<br />

Gives best price 67 101 102 110 380<br />

Trust/relationship 12 16 30 12 70<br />

Owe money to him 0 2 0 0 2<br />

Other 19 9 5 2 35<br />

Total 102 135 158 124 519<br />

Two other questions were used to explore the relationship between the farm household <strong>and</strong><br />

the most important buyer (in value terms). When asked how many years the household has sold to<br />

this buyer, 28 percent of the respondents said this was the first year <strong>and</strong> 43 percent said just a few<br />

years. This suggests that not only do farmers sell in spot markets for the most part, but there is a lot<br />

of turnover in the farmer-buyer relationship. This is positive in demonstrating that farmers have a<br />

choice <strong>and</strong> are not locked into a relationship, but it is also a matter of concern because it indicates that<br />

buyers are not likely to provide assistance (in the form of market information, credit, or inputs) to<br />

farmers under these conditions.<br />

Table 5-36. Number of years selling to buyer by accessibility category<br />

Number of years<br />

Accessibility<br />

selling to buyer Low 2 3 High Total<br />

Many years 7 11 3 9 7<br />

Several years 17 16 22 30 21<br />

Just a few years 30 44 55 39 43<br />

This was first year 46 29 21 21 28<br />

Total 100 100 100 100 100<br />

When asked how much the respondent trusts that they are getting a “fair price” from the<br />

buyer, 37 percent reported that they trust the buyer to give a fair price <strong>and</strong> another 58 percent state<br />

that they “trust the buyer more or less but verify prices.” Just 4 percent said they “don’t trust much”<br />

or “don’t trust at all.”<br />

Table 5-37. Trust in buyer by accessibility category<br />

Accessibility<br />

Trust in buyer Low 2 3 High Total<br />

Trust for fair price 40 42 36 29 37<br />

Trust but verify 49 53 61 68 58<br />

Don’t trust much 11 5 2 0 4<br />

Don’t trust at all 0 0 1 4 1<br />

Total 57 60 84 56 257<br />

100 100. 100 100 100<br />

Finally, respondents were asked whether a private trader or processor had ever given the<br />

household any encouragement or assistance to try a new crop. Given the results presented earlier, it is<br />

not surprising that 99 percent of the respondents said no.<br />

In summary, the bad news is that there is little or no “vertical coordination” between farmers<br />

<strong>and</strong> buyers. Farmers sell on spot markets <strong>and</strong> receive virtually no guidance (much less credit or other<br />

Page 125


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

assistance) from buyers regarding market opportunities. The good news is that farmers usually have a<br />

choice of buyers <strong>and</strong> seem to trust that the prices they receive are fair. On the basis of farmer<br />

perceptions, there is little evidence of exploitative relationships between farmers <strong>and</strong> buyers, even in<br />

the more remote villages.<br />

5.7 Role of government<br />

Earlier, we presented results indicating that, in about 40 percent of the cases where farmers<br />

adopted a new crop, the main factor in the decision was the encouragement or assistance of an<br />

extension agent or local authority. In this section, we examine in more detail the role of the<br />

government in promoting income diversification among rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

The households in the survey had relatively good contact with the extension service. About<br />

41 percent had attended an extension meeting in the past 12 months. Of those that did not attend a<br />

meeting, 78 percent received extension information indirectly (e.g. through the village leader, a friend,<br />

a brochure, or a radio program). Furthermore, these figures did not vary much across income groups<br />

or accessibility categories. Higher-income farmers were somewhat more likely to attend meetings<br />

<strong>and</strong> receive extension information indirectly, but the differences were modest (see Table 5-39).<br />

Table 5-38. Received suggestions from extension<br />

Extension suggest<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

new crop Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

Yes 58 45 55 53<br />

No 42 55 45 47<br />

Total 100 100 100 100<br />

Over half (53 percent) of the households said they had received encouragement or assistance<br />

from extension agents or other government officials to try a new crop. Of those receiving some kind<br />

of encouragement or assistance, almost all (97 percent) said they were shown how to grow the crop,<br />

more than half (59 percent) were provided with inputs for sale, <strong>and</strong> somewhat less than half (41<br />

percent) were provided inputs for free or on credit. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, only 8 percent were offered a<br />

marketing agreement <strong>and</strong> almost none (3 percent) were offered marketing information. Thus, it<br />

appears that the assistance provided was heavily oriented toward production, with little attention to<br />

marketing issues.<br />

Table 5-29. Types of assistance given to farmers<br />

Type of assistance Number Percent<br />

Show how to grow 155 97<br />

Provided inputs for sale 90 59<br />

Provided inputs free on credit 63 41<br />

Marketing information 4 3<br />

Marketing agreement 12 8<br />

Note: Total sums to more than 100 percent because respondents were<br />

allowed to give up to three responses.<br />

Overall, 75 percent of the respondents reported that they felt the assistance was “useful”.<br />

This percentage did not vary substantially between lower- <strong>and</strong> high-income households, nor between<br />

Page 126


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

households in remote <strong>and</strong> accessible villages. Among those who said it was useful, most of them<br />

reported good yields <strong>and</strong> higher income as a result of the assistance. Of those who said it was not<br />

useful, some complained of insufficient assistance, while others cited production problems (lack of<br />

water, poor yields) <strong>and</strong> marketing problems (the price was too low). Some noted that the seed<br />

provided by the extension service was of poor quality.<br />

Table 5-30. Usefulness of the assistance<br />

Was it<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

useful Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

Yes 81 73 71 75<br />

No 19 27 29 25<br />

Total 100 100 100 100<br />

The extension service <strong>and</strong> other local government officials were much less involved in<br />

providing assistance or encouragement to households to do non-crop activities. Only 11 percent of<br />

the respondents reported assistance or encouragement of this type. Of the 33 farmers who received<br />

assistance, most reported production information <strong>and</strong> credit, while very few reported assistance or<br />

information in marketing. As in the case of crop assistance, about three-quarters of the beneficiaries<br />

said the information was useful.<br />

Table 5-31. Respondent was encouraged to try new activity by extension agent<br />

Extension suggests<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

new activity Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

Yes 16 8 9 11<br />

No 84 92 91 89<br />

Total 100 100 100 100<br />

Finally, respondents were asked to identify up to three of the most useful types of government<br />

assistance to reduce poverty. Two-thirds of the households (68 percent) said that improved access to<br />

credit is a key strategy for reducing poverty. Over half (58 percent) called for better support for<br />

existing crops, while the promotion of new crops was mentioned by 36 percent. Also cited by at least<br />

one-third of the respondents was build or exp<strong>and</strong> irrigation <strong>and</strong> improve road to village. Better<br />

education <strong>and</strong> health care <strong>and</strong> electrification were each mentioned by at least 10 percent of the<br />

respondents (see Table 5-32 <strong>and</strong> Figure 5-7).<br />

Table 5-32. Most useful types of government assistance<br />

Most useful types of assistance Number Percent<br />

of responses of households<br />

Better education <strong>and</strong> health care 46 15<br />

Build better road to village 106 35<br />

Build or exp<strong>and</strong> irrigation 110 36<br />

Exp<strong>and</strong> or improve electrification 41 13<br />

Improve access to clean water 18 6<br />

Better access to credit 209 68<br />

Promote new crops & marketing 111 36<br />

Better support for existing crops 177 58<br />

Promote non-farm employment 14 5<br />

Other 56 18<br />

Total 888 289<br />

Note: Total sums to more than 100 percent because respondents were<br />

allowed to give up to three responses.<br />

Page 127


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Figure 5-7. Most useful types of government assistance<br />

Credit<br />

Support existing crops<br />

Irrigation<br />

New crops<br />

Roads<br />

Education/health<br />

Electrification<br />

Non-farm activities<br />

% of responses<br />

0% 20% 40% 60% 80%<br />

There were some differences on priorities across income terciles. Lower-income households<br />

were somewhat more likely to call for electrification <strong>and</strong> clean water, probably because they are<br />

mostly likely not to have these amenities. Higher-income households were more likely to mention<br />

health <strong>and</strong> education. But all three income categories mentioned improved access to credit <strong>and</strong> better<br />

support for existing crops as their first <strong>and</strong> second priorities, respectively (see Table 5-33)<br />

Table 5-33. Most useful types of government assistance by income tercile<br />

Most useful types<br />

<strong>Income</strong> tercile<br />

of assistance Lower Middle Upper Total<br />

(percent of responses)<br />

Better education & health care 3 5 7 5<br />

Build better road to village 13 10 13 12<br />

Build or exp<strong>and</strong> irrigation 10 15 12 12<br />

Exp<strong>and</strong> or improve electrification 8 3 3 5<br />

Improve access to clean water 4 1 1 2<br />

Better access to credit 23 24 23 24<br />

Promote new crops & marketing 11 14 13 13<br />

Better support for existing crops 22 23 15 20<br />

Promote non-farm employment 1 1 3 2<br />

Other 4 4 10 6<br />

Total 100 100 100 100<br />

Some differences were also observed between the responses of households in remote villages<br />

<strong>and</strong> those in accessible villages. Not surprisingly, better roads were mentioned by 14 percent of those<br />

in isolated villages but just 4 percent of those in accessible villages. Similarly, electrification <strong>and</strong><br />

clean water were cited by a higher proportion of households in remote villages. On the other h<strong>and</strong>,<br />

improved credit was mentioned by 30 percent of those in the most accessible category but just 18<br />

percent of those in the least accessible category. But similarities remain. In three out of the four<br />

accessibility categories, credit <strong>and</strong> support to existing crops are the two most important priorities for<br />

rural households.<br />

Page 128


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Table 5-34. Most useful types of government assistance by accessibility<br />

Most useful types<br />

Accessibility<br />

of assistance Low 2 3 High Total<br />

(percent of responses)<br />

Better education & health care 3 5 9 1 5<br />

Build better road to village 14 14 13 4 12<br />

Build or exp<strong>and</strong> irrigation 13 5 21 8 12<br />

Exp<strong>and</strong> or improve electrification 8 9 0 1 5<br />

Improve access to clean water 5 2 0 1 2<br />

Better access to credit 18 25 22 30 24<br />

Promote new crops & marketing 13 15 7 18 13<br />

Better support for existing crops 20 20 18 23 20<br />

Promote non-farm employment 0 1 3 2 2<br />

Other 5 4 6 12 6<br />

Total 100 100 100 100 100<br />

5.8 Case studies<br />

In order to complement the statistics provided in the previous sections, we present a number<br />

of case studies. These examples give a more tangible idea of the challenges faced by rural households<br />

in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

Case 1: Nguyễn Quang Vinh is a 43 years old farmer with a seventh grade education. He is<br />

from the Tày ethnic minority <strong>and</strong> lives in Lương Thịnh commune, Trấn Yên district, Yên Bái<br />

province. He <strong>and</strong> his wife <strong>and</strong> two children were allocated two hectares of hilly forest l<strong>and</strong>. On that<br />

l<strong>and</strong>, he plants tea, cinnamon, <strong>and</strong> styrax. His family harvests six tons of tea per year. The current<br />

price of tea is VND 1700-1800/kg, so their annual gross revenue from tea production is about VND<br />

10 million.<br />

Case 2: Hoàng Thị Thu is 26 years old <strong>and</strong> finished grade 8. She is also from the Tày ethnic<br />

minority <strong>and</strong> lives in Cường Lợi commune, Đình Lập district, Lạng Sơn province. She lives with her<br />

husb<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> her four-year-old child. She is 8 months pregnant. Her family, newly formed, has no<br />

l<strong>and</strong>. In the absence of l<strong>and</strong>, her husb<strong>and</strong> works as motorbike driver. She herself stays at home to<br />

raise chickens <strong>and</strong> pigs. Every year in the dry season, some paddy fields stay fallow. She borrows<br />

1000 m 2 of l<strong>and</strong> from her parents <strong>and</strong> relatives to grow maize <strong>and</strong> cassava for the animals. Ms. Thu<br />

said that raising pigs <strong>and</strong> chickens provides her with a high <strong>and</strong> stable income, but because she lacks<br />

capital <strong>and</strong> knowledge about breeding <strong>and</strong> disease prevention, she is reluctant to exp<strong>and</strong>. Early this<br />

year she borrowed money from her relatives to buy three piglets. The piglets became sick, <strong>and</strong>,<br />

because there are no veterinary workers nearby, she bought medicine based on the suggestion of<br />

neighbors. Two piglets died, <strong>and</strong> she is now in debt.<br />

Case 3: Đặng Lâm Thao is 52 years old <strong>and</strong> from the Kinh group. He is chairman of the<br />

Trạm Tấu People Committee, Yên Bái province. He reports that the H’Mông people here have a<br />

tradition of growing flax <strong>and</strong> weaving. In addition, the climate <strong>and</strong> soil in this area are very suitable to<br />

flax cultivation. However, this activity has fallen into neglect. If there is a market for it, if there is<br />

enough capital, <strong>and</strong> if the roads are in good condition, this activity could be developed, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

income of H'mong people in the area would be improved.<br />

Page 129


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Case 4: Nguyen Quang Vinh, a former solder, has two hectares of hilly l<strong>and</strong>. He is curious to<br />

learn new agricultural methods. He has invested VND 15 million to dig a fish pond <strong>and</strong> raise<br />

chickens. He was interested in learning how to graft litchi <strong>and</strong> longan. When asked about measures to<br />

promote the transformation of cropping patterns, he said the government should give thorough<br />

technical guidance on how to cultivate a crop, how to raise animals, <strong>and</strong> organize study tours for<br />

farmers so that they see examples of good practices with their own eyes. According to Vinh,<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing the market is an important factor in diversification.<br />

Case 5: Dang Xuan Bao lives in Cuong Loi commune, Dinh Lap district, Lang Son province.<br />

He is one of the main innovators in his commune, having tried various new crops. He was the first in<br />

the village to grow watermelon when it became evident that there was a market for it in China. In the<br />

first year, due to lack of experience, his yield was low but the high price helped him to cover costs. In<br />

2000, he has exp<strong>and</strong>ed the area <strong>and</strong> the yield improved, but he was unable to sell the output to China.<br />

He has to sell at low price or leave the watermelon to rot in the field. Last year, he grew chili because<br />

there was a strong dem<strong>and</strong> for chili, but at harvest the dem<strong>and</strong> had disappeared <strong>and</strong> his chili rotted in<br />

the field. Like other farmers, production risk <strong>and</strong> marketing risk make him reluctant to diversify into<br />

new crops.<br />

Case 6: Vi Thi Sinh, 55 years old, lives in Cuong Loi commune, Dinh Lap district, Lang Son<br />

province. When electricity came to the village in 1999, she became involved in grain milling. In<br />

order to buy the mill, she had sell a buffalo because she could not borrow money from anyone. At<br />

beginning, there was a good number of customers so the business was profitable, but at present most<br />

of households have mini-processing machines made in China <strong>and</strong> the number of customers gone<br />

down rapidly. She has begun raising pigs in order to utilize the rice bran <strong>and</strong> increase her profits.<br />

Case 7: Huynh Thi Mw is a 33-year old from the Kinh ethnic group, resettled in Viet Lam<br />

commune, Vi Xuyen district. Her family has been resettled since 1995 <strong>and</strong> started to cultivate<br />

mulberry. Initially, business was very bad <strong>and</strong> unstable with series of difficulties, but they consulted<br />

the Hanoi Center for Mulberry <strong>and</strong> Silkworm Development. The Center provided training <strong>and</strong> seed<br />

(silkworm egg) <strong>and</strong> some staff comes to buy the cocoons. Since then, mulberry production has been<br />

profitable. Her family has exp<strong>and</strong>ed the business into selling silkworm seed egg at a price of VND<br />

20,000 per ring (imported from the center in Hanoi) <strong>and</strong> collecting cocoons from farmers. Then, they<br />

transport the cocoons by bus to sell to the Center in Hanoi.<br />

Case 8: Le The Dung, from Luc Ngan district, Bac Giang province, is 34 years old <strong>and</strong><br />

completed the National Economics University. He has been involved in litchi for many years, with<br />

current capital of about VND 300 million. Having discovered the importance of litchi storage, he has<br />

contacted the Post-Harvest Technology Institute to find the way to store litchi longer. He learned how<br />

to store litchi using ozone water for a longer time. He has also guided <strong>and</strong> advised many households<br />

in the hamlet with this technique.<br />

Page 130


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

Case 9: Nguyen Thi Tuyen, a 55-year-old woman in Viet Lam commune, Vi Xuyen district,<br />

Ha Giang province, is involving in milling “My family has always wanted to exp<strong>and</strong> livestock in<br />

order to use rice bran from grain milling, but we don’t have the funds to do this… The interest rate of<br />

private lenders is very high. The government should revise this policy to encourage households to<br />

invest <strong>and</strong> produce”.<br />

Case 10: The H’Mong family of Ha Thi Dua in Phieng Khoai commune, Yen Chau district<br />

moved from their parent’s home five years ago. The commune gave them 4900 m 2 for cultivation<br />

(400 m 2 of lowl<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> 4500 m 2 of upl<strong>and</strong> fields). Noticing that there was still a lot of unused l<strong>and</strong> in<br />

the commune, they asked for <strong>and</strong> received another 10,000 m 2 of l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> used it to grow maize. With<br />

encouragement from the extension service officers, they used the maize variety LVN10 <strong>and</strong> obtained<br />

yields three times greater than the traditional variety. With such good results, they decided to lease<br />

more l<strong>and</strong> (20,000 m 2 ) <strong>and</strong> paid VND 500.000 per year/per hectare. Each year since 1999, they have<br />

been able to harvest about ten tons of maize, six ton of cannas, three tons of cassava, <strong>and</strong> 200 kg of<br />

pork with the net income of VND 18 millions. In 2000, they bought a truck worth VND 25 millions to<br />

transport their output <strong>and</strong> to rent out. Every year, she earns VND 4 millions from the rental. Today<br />

they are trying to replace cassava with fruit trees in order to make their income higher. There were<br />

another three H’Mong families in the same village who did similar things <strong>and</strong> also own a truck.<br />

5.9 Summary<br />

The results of the QSAID Household Survey confirm the finding from the VLSS data that<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards of living in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s have improved for the vast majority of rural<br />

households. Fully 83 percent of the QSAID respondents said that their st<strong>and</strong>ard of living was higher<br />

today than in 1994 <strong>and</strong> just 1 percent (3 households) reported a deterioration. Most households (62<br />

percent) reported that their own food production was enough to supply them for 12 months per year<br />

<strong>and</strong> about two-thirds (69 percent) said that they did not experience any hungry months over the course<br />

of the year. When asked about the reasons for their improved st<strong>and</strong>ard of living, 80 percent cited<br />

higher crop yields, 62 percent mentioned higher livestock income, <strong>and</strong> 47 percent said that they now<br />

grow new, more profitable crops. The importance of yield increases in income growth confirms the<br />

results of the VLSS, though the importance of livestock income <strong>and</strong> crop diversification seems greater<br />

in the QSAID than would be expected based on the VLSS analysis. Part of the explanation may be<br />

that the QSAID uses a difference reference period (1994-2002) than the VLSS analysis (1993-98).<br />

The poorest respondents were more likely to attribute income gains to higher yields, while their<br />

higher-income neighbors were more likely to credit crop diversification <strong>and</strong> diversification into nonfarm<br />

activities. These results also mirror those obtained from the VLSS.<br />

Staple food crops remain important in rural livelihoods, however. Ninety-one percent of the<br />

respondents said that rice was among the top three sources of income. Pigs, maize, <strong>and</strong> poultry were<br />

Page 131


Chapter 5: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> from the Farmers’ Perspective<br />

listed among the top three sources by over 70 percent of the households. Non-farm income was<br />

somewhat more common among higher-income households than poorer households.<br />

An impressive 83 percent of the respondents had adopted at least one new crop or source of<br />

income since 1994, the most common ones being litchi, other fruit, tea, <strong>and</strong> “other industrial crops”.<br />

Fewer households reported giving up a crop or income source, the most common ones being cassava,<br />

beans, <strong>and</strong> opium. Farmers report that the share of income from rice, maize, pigs, buffalo, tea, <strong>and</strong><br />

litchi has increased, while that of cassava, poultry, <strong>and</strong> firewood has decreased. Fifty-six percent had<br />

successfully adopted at least one new crop (where success is defined by continued cultivation),<br />

although this is considerably less common among poor <strong>and</strong> remote households. Tea, litchi, anise, <strong>and</strong><br />

new varieties of rice were the most frequently mentioned. Friends <strong>and</strong> extension agents are most<br />

commonly credited with encouraging the adoption of the new crop <strong>and</strong> farmers received inputs on<br />

sale or on credit in over half the cases. About one-quarter reported unsuccessful experiences with<br />

new crops, with plum <strong>and</strong> apricot being mentioned most frequently.<br />

Regarding the role of traders, there appears to be little or no “vertical coordination” between<br />

farmers <strong>and</strong> buyers. Farmers sell on spot markets <strong>and</strong> receive virtually no guidance or any other<br />

assistance from buyers. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, farmers generally have a choice of buyers <strong>and</strong> seem to<br />

trust that the prices they receive are fair. There is little evidence of exploitative relationships, even in<br />

the least accessible villages.<br />

Extension agents <strong>and</strong> local government officials are quite involved in the process of<br />

diversification. Over half the rural households interviewed had received guidance or assistance on<br />

new crops from an extension agent, <strong>and</strong> three-quarter felt the assistance was useful. The respondents<br />

had clear views on what types of activities could help the poor. Three-quarters (72 percent) agreed<br />

that raising fish or livestock would help the poor; about half (52 percent) said that growing different<br />

crops would help; but just 18 percent said that small businesses or wage income would assist the poor<br />

raise their incomes. Regarding the constraints, the most common response was “lack of capital”, but<br />

lack of labor, animal disease, lack of seed/seedlings, <strong>and</strong> lack of pasture were also cited. When asked<br />

about the most useful forms of government intervention, 24 percent said better access to credit, 20<br />

percent cited better support for existing crops, <strong>and</strong> 12 percent mentioned promotion of new crops.<br />

Among the most remote villages, greater weight was put on infrastructure improvements (roads,<br />

water, <strong>and</strong> electricity) <strong>and</strong> less weight on credit.<br />

Page 132


CHAPTER SIX<br />

DIVERSIFICATION FROM THE PERSPECTIVE OF LOCAL GOVERNMENT<br />

Local government plays a key role in the process of income <strong>and</strong> crop diversification.<br />

Although development targets, agricultural policies, <strong>and</strong> major public investment decisions are made<br />

in Hanoi, provincial <strong>and</strong> district authorities are responsible for implementing these policies <strong>and</strong><br />

programs. Differences across provinces in administrative, financial, <strong>and</strong> technical capacity mean that<br />

the implementation differs across provinces.<br />

The goal of the Qualitative Social Assessment of <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> (QSAID) was to<br />

study the process of income diversification to identify constraints <strong>and</strong> opportunities as perceived by<br />

key participants in the process: farmers, local authorities, traders, <strong>and</strong> processors. In this section, we<br />

describe the results of the interviews with local authorities.<br />

6.1 Methods<br />

Before describing the results, it is useful to provide a brief overview of the methods used to<br />

collect the information. The interview guidelines for the provincial <strong>and</strong> district officials consisted of<br />

24 questions <strong>and</strong> one table to complete (see Appendix C). The questions covered topics related to the<br />

patterns of crop <strong>and</strong> income diversification in the province or district, the factors that catalyze the<br />

introduction of new crops, the role <strong>and</strong> policies of the local authorities in promoting new crops, the<br />

role of private traders in promoting new crops, <strong>and</strong> the role of state-owned enterprises in stimulating<br />

diversification. The table requested a simple high-medium-low classification of the degree of market<br />

access <strong>and</strong> the st<strong>and</strong>ard of living of the administrative units within the province or district, along with<br />

a brief summary of the main crops or activities that have exp<strong>and</strong>ed since 1994 <strong>and</strong> the main obstacles<br />

to development. These questions were designed to be the starting point for open-ended discussion of<br />

the process of income diversification in the province/district <strong>and</strong> the role of the government in<br />

promoting it.<br />

The interview guidelines for the commune authorities followed the format of the household<br />

questionnaire (see Appendix B). As such, it involved somewhat longer <strong>and</strong> less open-ended<br />

interviews. Furthermore, it focused more closely on the experience of farmers within the commune<br />

with new crops <strong>and</strong> new activities.<br />

As discussed in Chapters 1 <strong>and</strong> 5, the Qualitative Social Assessment of <strong>Income</strong><br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> (QSAID) collected data in eight of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> province. The eight<br />

provinces were selected to represent the diversity of the region in terms of market access (proximity<br />

to Hanoi), topography (lowl<strong>and</strong> vs. upl<strong>and</strong>), <strong>and</strong> geography (east vs. west). Two districts were<br />

selected from each province. One district was chosen close to the main roads or a major city, while<br />

the other was more remote. The selection of districts also took into account the ethnic composition of<br />

the districts in order to ensure that the districts were representative of the province. In each of the 16<br />

Page 133


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

selected districts, one commune was selected r<strong>and</strong>omly to be visited. Table 6-1 shows the list of<br />

provinces, districts, <strong>and</strong> communes included in the QSAID.<br />

Table 6-1: Provinces, districts, <strong>and</strong> communes selected for Qualitative Social Assessment<br />

of <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

Province code Province District/commune<br />

code<br />

District Commune Hardship<br />

factor<br />

1 Yen Bai 1 Tram Tau Xa Ho 0.7<br />

1 Yen Bai 2 Tran Yen Luong Thinh 0.3<br />

2 Ha Giang 1 Dong Van Van Chai 0.7<br />

2 Ha Giang 2 Vi Xuyen Viet Lam 0.5<br />

3 Lang Son 1 Dinh Lap Cuong Loi 0.4<br />

3 Lang Son 2 Van Quan Trang Phat 0.3<br />

4 Bac Giang 1 Luc Ngan Bien Son 0.1<br />

4 Bac Giang 2 Luc Nam Nghia Phuong 0.1<br />

5 Thai Nguyen 1 Phu Luong Phan Me 0.1<br />

5 Thai Nguyen 2 Vo Nhai Dan Tien 0.4<br />

6 Bac Kan 1 Ngan Son Thuong Quan 0.7<br />

6 Bac Kan 2 Choi Moi Nong Ha 0.3<br />

7 Son La 1 Yen Chau Phieng Khoai 0.5<br />

7 Son La 2 Thuan Chau Chieng Bom 0.5<br />

8 Lai Chau 1 Muang Lay Cha To 0.5<br />

8 Lai Chau 2 Dien Bien Dong Keo Lom 0.7<br />

The interviews were carried out by two teams of three Vietnamese researchers, each<br />

consisting of a more senior team leader <strong>and</strong> two associates. An international consultant <strong>and</strong> two staff<br />

members from the International Food Policy Research Institute worked with the local researchers in<br />

selecting the sample <strong>and</strong> designing <strong>and</strong> testing the interview guidelines. IFPRI staff <strong>and</strong> the<br />

consultant also accompanied the local researchers during the first two weeks of field work <strong>and</strong> made<br />

periodic visits to the field teams throughout the field work. The field work took place between late<br />

July <strong>and</strong> early October 2002.<br />

After the data collection phase, the two teams were responsible for summarizing the results of<br />

their interviews. This chapter is based on the field notes <strong>and</strong> on two background reports prepared by<br />

the two teams of field researchers.<br />

Page 134


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

6.2 Patterns in diversification<br />

The local authorities interviewed as part of the Qualitative Social Assessment are almost<br />

unanimous in their view that the types of crops grown by farmers has changed since 1994, though the<br />

types of change vary from place to place.<br />

The adoption of hybrid maize on a large scale was mentioned by officials in several provinces<br />

<strong>and</strong> districts. For example, it is estimated that 40-50 percent of the maize area in Bac Kan is planted<br />

with hybrid maize. In Bac Giang, hybrid maize is said to have completely replaced the use of retained<br />

seed. New maize varieties or exp<strong>and</strong>ed maize area was also cited by officials in Lai Chau, Son La, Ha<br />

Giang, <strong>and</strong> Lang Son, as well as many district officials. As described earlier, the most dramatic<br />

increase in maize production has been in Son La, which has more than doubled its maize output over<br />

1995-2000.<br />

Numerous provincial <strong>and</strong> district officials reported that farmers were adopting <strong>and</strong>/or<br />

exp<strong>and</strong>ing production of various types of fruit trees. In Bac Kan, apricot, persimmons, peach, <strong>and</strong><br />

mango areas are increasing. In Lang Son, officials also cited the expansion of fruit production. But<br />

Bac Giang is the lead fruit producer in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. In this province, litchi area has grown<br />

from 270 hectares in 1990 to 32 thous<strong>and</strong> hectares today, one third of which is not yet mature. Under<br />

a project to provide pineapples for a new processing plant, the pineapple area in Bac Giang is<br />

schedule to increase from 1400 hectares in 2001 to 38 thous<strong>and</strong> hectares. Persimmons were not<br />

grown in the province before 1996, but there are now 1300 hectares of persimmons.<br />

Five of the eight provinces report that more farmers are growing tea. Yen Bai is the lead tea<br />

producer in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> is second only to Lam Dong (Southeast) on a national level.<br />

Yen Bai, Thai Nguyen, <strong>and</strong> Phu Tho produce two-thirds of the tea in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> onethird<br />

of the tea in Vietnam.<br />

Other crops mentioned in interviews with local authorities include anise, cinamon, cardomon,<br />

sugarcane, coffee, bamboo, flax, tobacco, soybeans, <strong>and</strong> rice. Only a few official reported increase in<br />

rice area, although officials in in Bac Kan noted that high-yield varieties of rice have been adopted<br />

widely by farmers so that these varieties now account for 70-80 percent of the rice area.<br />

Looking at the new crops by province, we see that Bac Giang <strong>and</strong> Thai Nguyen, the two<br />

provinces in our sample that are closest to Hanoi <strong>and</strong> the delta, have experienced significant<br />

expansion of litchi <strong>and</strong> longan. Thai Nguyen also had an increase in sugarcane, while Bac Giang<br />

reports a wide variety of new crops including pineapple, persimmons, custard apple, pig, <strong>and</strong> poultry<br />

production. Authorities in<br />

Bac Giang report the widest array of new crops <strong>and</strong> activities among the eight provinces visited see<br />

Table 6-2 <strong>and</strong> Table 6-3).<br />

Page 135


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

Table 6-2. Characteristics of districts in selected provinces as perceived by provincial authorities<br />

Province (in<br />

bold) <strong>and</strong> district<br />

Market<br />

access<br />

1 Poor<br />

2 Avg<br />

3 Good<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

of living<br />

1 Very<br />

poor<br />

2 Poor<br />

3 Fair<br />

Main crops or activities that have<br />

increased in importance since 1994<br />

Main constraints to agricultural<br />

development<br />

Thai Nguyen<br />

1. Dai Tu 2 1 Litchi, longan Transport, lack of intensification<br />

2. Dinh Hoa 1 1 None Inconvenient transport;<br />

3. Phu Luong 2 2 Litchi, longan Lack of processing, fragmented prod.<br />

4. Vo Nhai 1 1 Sugarcane Transport; backward production;<br />

5. Dong Hy 3 2 Litchi, longan, sugarcane, mulberry Lack of experience <strong>and</strong> capital<br />

6. Phu Binh 2 2 Litchi, longan Lack of experience <strong>and</strong> capital<br />

7. Pho Yen 2 2 Litchi, longan, sugarcane No market, poor soils<br />

8. Song Cong 3 2 None Limitation in cultivated l<strong>and</strong><br />

town<br />

9. Thai Nguyen 3 3 Litchi, longan Lack of l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> capital.<br />

city<br />

Bac Can<br />

1. Ba Be 1 1 Maize, soybean, rice Lack of capital, skills, l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

2. Na Ri 1 2 Tobacco, maize, rice Lack of capital, skills, l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

3. Ngan Son 1 1 Tobacco, maize, rice, soybean Lack of capital, skills, l<strong>and</strong>, labor<br />

4. Cho Moi 1 1 Tuyet Shan tea, maize Lack of l<strong>and</strong>, skills, capital.<br />

5. Cho Don 1 1 Tuyet Shan tea, maize, cinnamon Lack of l<strong>and</strong>, capital, transport.<br />

6. Bach Thong 1 1 Maize, rice Lack of capital, skills, l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

7. Town 2 3 Maize, rice Lack of l<strong>and</strong>, markets<br />

Son La<br />

1. Moc Chau 3 2 Tea, hybrid maize Lack of capital, skills, big families<br />

2. Yen Chau 2 2 Sugarcane, hybrid maize Lack of capital, skills, l<strong>and</strong><br />

3. Mai Son 3 2 Sugarcane, coffee, mulbery Lack of capital, skills, labor, big families<br />

4. Son La town 3 3 Chicken Lack of capital, experience, l<strong>and</strong><br />

5. Thuan Chau 1 1 Coffee Lack of capital, skills, large families<br />

6. Quynh Nhai 1 2 None Lack of capital, skills<br />

7. Muong La 1 2 None Lack of capital, skills, big families<br />

8. Bac Yen 2 1 Sugarcane Lack of capital, skills, big families<br />

9. Phu Yen 2 1 Fish Lack of capital, skills, l<strong>and</strong><br />

10. Song Ma 1 1 None Lack of capital, skills, labor; big families .<br />

Yen Bai<br />

1. Yen Bai city 3 3 None None<br />

2. Luc Yen 2 3 None Lack of markets<br />

3. Yen Binh 3 3 Tea Lack of markets<br />

4. Tran Yen 2 3 Tea, mulbery Lack of markets; lack of l<strong>and</strong> for<br />

cultivation<br />

5. Van Yen 2 3 Tea Lack of market;<br />

6. Mu Cang Chai 1 1 Tea Lack of market; difficult to transport<br />

7. Tram Tau 1 1 Tea, fruit trees, pine Lack of market; difficult to transport<br />

8. Van Chan 2 2 Tea, pine Lack of market; difficult to transport<br />

9. Nghia Lo<br />

town<br />

3 3 None None<br />

Source: Interviews with provincial representatives of DARD <strong>and</strong> DOLISA.<br />

Page 136


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

Table 6-3. Characteristics of districts in selected provinces as perceived by provincial authorities<br />

Province (in bold) <strong>and</strong><br />

district<br />

Market<br />

access<br />

1 Poor<br />

2 Avg<br />

3 Good<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

of living<br />

1 V poor<br />

2 Poor<br />

3 Fair<br />

Main crops or activities that have<br />

increased in importance since 1994<br />

Main constraints to agricultural<br />

development<br />

Ha Giang<br />

1. Dong Van 1 1 Maize HQ1; tea Lack of water; lack of l<strong>and</strong><br />

2. Meo Vac 1 1 Maize HQ1; tea Lack of water; lack of l<strong>and</strong><br />

3. Yen Minh 1 2 Maize HQ1; so Lack of water; lack of l<strong>and</strong><br />

4. Quan Ba 1 1 Maize Lack of water; lack of l<strong>and</strong><br />

5. Bac Me 1 2 Orange; m<strong>and</strong>arin Transportation<br />

6. Ha Giang town 2 3<br />

7. Vi Xuyen 2 2 Longan, bamboo Transportation<br />

8. Hoang Su Phi 1 1 Maize Transportation<br />

9. Xiu Man 1 1 Maize Transportation<br />

10. Bac Quang 2 2 Orange; m<strong>and</strong>arin Transportation<br />

Lang Son<br />

1. Lang Son town 3 3 hybrid rice<br />

2. Cao Loc 2 2 None Market<br />

3. Van lang 1 2 None Market<br />

4. Trang dinh 1 2 None Market<br />

5. Van Quan 1 2 Anise Market<br />

6. Binh Gia 1 2 Cattle raising Market<br />

7. Bac Son 1 2 M<strong>and</strong>arin Market<br />

8. Loc Binh 3 3 Cattle raising Market<br />

9. Dinh Lap 1 2 Cattle raising Water; transport<br />

10. Chi Lang 2 2 Custard apple Market<br />

11. Huu Lung 3 3 Persimmon Market<br />

Lai Chau<br />

1. Muong Te 1 1 None Transportation<br />

2. Muong Nhe 1 1 None Transportation<br />

3. Phong Tho 1 1 Cardamom Transportation<br />

4. Tam Duong 1 2 None Transportation<br />

5. Sin Ho 1 1 None Transportation<br />

6. Lai Chau town 2 2 None<br />

7. Muong Lay 1 1 sugarcane, cardamom Transportation, flooding<br />

8. Tua Chua 1 1 Tuyet Shan tea Transportation<br />

9. Tuan Giao 2 2 Soybean Transportation<br />

10. Dien Bien 2 3 Fruit trees Transportation<br />

11. Dien Bien Dong 1 1 None Transportation, hills, flooding<br />

12. Dien Bien Phu town 3 3 Chicken raising Transportation<br />

Bac Giang<br />

1. Bac Giang town 3 3 Fishery; flower, bonsai Marketing<br />

2. Viet Yen 3 2 Pig, cattle, fish, turtle, bamboo, rattan<br />

goods<br />

Lack of l<strong>and</strong>; rats, markets,<br />

fragmentation, disease<br />

3. Yen Dung 1 2 Litchi, chicken, pig, cattle; Marketing, processing<br />

4. Hiep Hoa 1 2 Livestock, fishery, peanut, soybean; Marketing, processing<br />

5. Luc Ngan 2 3 Litchi, persimmon, processing Marketing<br />

6. Luc Nam 2 3 Litchi, pineapple, custard apple, service,<br />

processing<br />

Marketing<br />

7. Tan Yen 3 3 Litchi, pineapple, maize, peanut Marketing, processing<br />

8. Yen The 1 2 Litchi, pineapple, special animals, forest Marketing of products;<br />

planting<br />

transport<br />

9. Lang Giang 2 Litchi, pineapple Marketing of products<br />

10. Son Dong 1 Litchi, longan, forest planting Irrigation, roads, water,<br />

climate, market for products<br />

Source: Interviews with provincial representatives of DARD <strong>and</strong> DOLISA.<br />

In Bac Kan, rice, maize, tobacco, <strong>and</strong> tea are reported to be exp<strong>and</strong>ing in several districts<br />

each. In Yen Bai, tea expansion is cited in six of the eight rural districts. In Son La, increases in<br />

maize <strong>and</strong> sugarcane production are reported in several districts, which is not surprising given the<br />

dramatic growth in maize production according to agricultural statistics (GSO, 2001a). These three<br />

Page 137


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

provinces, Ha Giang, Lang Son, <strong>and</strong> Lai Chau may be considered to have intermediate market access.<br />

Unlike Thai Nguyen <strong>and</strong> Bac Giang, several districts in Son La <strong>and</strong> Yen Bai do not have any crops<br />

that have increased in importance since 1994. All three of the districts in Son La with no reported<br />

diversification are rated “poor” in market access by provincial authorities (see Table 6-2 <strong>and</strong> Table 6-<br />

3).<br />

The three provinces in the sample that are the most remote are Lao Cai, Ha Giang, <strong>and</strong> Lai<br />

Chau. Over half the districts are rated “poor” in market access by provincial authorities. In Ha<br />

Giang, the crops that are growing in importance are maize, tea, <strong>and</strong> citrus. In Lang Son, cattle<br />

production is said to be exp<strong>and</strong>ing in three provinces. In Lai Chau, cardamom, sugarcane, tea,<br />

soybean, fruit trees, <strong>and</strong> chicken are mentioned (see Table 6-2 <strong>and</strong> Table 6-3).<br />

These results indicate that some diversification is occurring in most districts of the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s, but the pace of diversification is greater in areas with good market access. The average<br />

number of new crops or activities listed by provincial authorities is 1.4 among districts with “poor”<br />

market access <strong>and</strong> 2.8 among districts with “good” market access. Furthermore, the type of<br />

diversification depends on the degree of market access. In provinces close to Hanoi <strong>and</strong> the delta,<br />

farmers are diversifying into litchi, longan, <strong>and</strong> other fruit crops. Farther out, farmers are diversifying<br />

into tea, sugarcane, <strong>and</strong> tobacco. And in the most remote provinces, any diversification that occurs<br />

tends to be into maize or cattle production.<br />

What are these new crops replacing Local officials were asked which crops were declining<br />

in importance. The most common responses were upl<strong>and</strong> rice, cassava, <strong>and</strong> sweet potato. However,<br />

it is too simplistic to view the trend as a shift from staple food crops to commercial crops. In some<br />

cases, the area under specific high-value crops is declining as farmers discover that the soils are not<br />

appropriate or in response to lower market prices. In Son La, the area planted with mulberry, apricot,<br />

<strong>and</strong> plum is said to be falling. In Bac Giang, the area under citrus is reported declining. Coffee<br />

growers in Ha Giang <strong>and</strong> elsewhere are discouraged by low international prices.<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> into higher-value crops is not occurring everywhere, however. <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

seems more common in areas with favorable conditions in term of soil <strong>and</strong> roads. In upl<strong>and</strong> districts<br />

that have bad roads, rocky soil, steep slopes, <strong>and</strong>/or poor irrigation (areas typically inhabited by the<br />

H’Mong people), there is much less likely to be crop diversification. This was the case for Trạm Tấu<br />

(Yên Bái) <strong>and</strong> Đồng Văn (Hà Giang), where there has been very little shift in cropping pattern. In<br />

these areas, the only cropping changes are the introduction of hybrid rice <strong>and</strong> maize with higher<br />

yields. These new varieties have improved food security, but often do not lead to increased marketed<br />

surplus. In addition, it is worth noting that six of the twelve districts in Lai Chau are said not to have<br />

any diversification, according to provincial officials. In 29 percent of the districts with “poor” market<br />

access, provincial authorities could not name a crop or activity whose importance has increased over<br />

time. In contrast, none of the districts with “good” market access were without new crops or activities<br />

(see Table 6-2 <strong>and</strong> Table 6-3).<br />

Page 138


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

There appears to be little diversification into livestock activities, according to local officials.<br />

There is little government support for exp<strong>and</strong>ing livestock production except in selected areas. One<br />

exception is Ha Giang, which has a program to promote cattle production. Of course, owning smallscale<br />

livestock is quite common. Many households have 1-2 pigs <strong>and</strong> some chickens for own<br />

consumption <strong>and</strong> occasional sale. But livestock development does not appear to be a high priority for<br />

local officials, <strong>and</strong> they are not aware of major changes in breeds, production methods, or innovation.<br />

This result contrasts with the household interviews in which farmers reported that pig production was<br />

one of the three most important factors in the improved living st<strong>and</strong>ards of their household since<br />

1994.<br />

Bac Giang has a large fruit sector, taking advantage of its relatively good soil <strong>and</strong> market<br />

access. The development of fruit production in the province has received assistance <strong>and</strong><br />

encouragement from local officials <strong>and</strong> extension officers. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the bee-keeping<br />

necessary to pollinate the trees has exp<strong>and</strong>ed spontaneously.<br />

Interviews with local officials also suggest that diversification into non-farm activities is rare,<br />

particularly in the more remote villages. In general, it is difficult for people in remote mountain<br />

villages to find jobs, particularly outside the agricultural sector. Most farmers <strong>and</strong> commune<br />

authorities were not able to provide any suggestions for promoting non-farm activities. The reasons<br />

given for this pattern are that there are no markets for non-farm goods, people do not have the<br />

education <strong>and</strong> skills for non-farm work, <strong>and</strong>, being isolated, it is difficult to work as hired labor in<br />

other areas. These results parallel those of the QSAID Household Survey, which found that few<br />

households had started non-farm enterprises since 1994 <strong>and</strong> few felt that non-farm enterprises were a<br />

promising way for poor households to raise their incomes.<br />

6.3 Role of government in promoting diversification<br />

Almost all the local officials attribute the adoption of new crops mainly to policies <strong>and</strong><br />

subsidies offered by the government. In Lai Chau, farmers are switching to modern irrigated-rice<br />

varieties partly because of the higher yields <strong>and</strong> partly because the government offers subsidies for<br />

new terracing 1 . Similarly, the adoption of hybrid maize is motivated by higher yields <strong>and</strong> by the fact<br />

that hybrid maize seed is subsidized. In Bac Kan <strong>and</strong> Son La, local officials described the adoption<br />

process as being influenced by both spontaneous decisions of farmers <strong>and</strong> government efforts to<br />

promote new crops. In Yen Bai, local officials reported that adoption of new crops was determined<br />

by “strategic direction” from the central government <strong>and</strong> said that there are no crops that farmers have<br />

spontaneously adopted. Similarly, officials in Ha Giang, Bac Giang, <strong>and</strong> Lang Son stressed the role<br />

of government programs <strong>and</strong> subsidies in determining the direction <strong>and</strong> extent of crop diversification.<br />

Various policies are used to promote diversification into new crops.<br />

1<br />

Under Decision 186/CP, farmers are given VND 5 million for each new hectare of terraced l<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Page 139


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

Input subsidies In every province visited, seeds <strong>and</strong> planting materials are subsidized or even<br />

provided to farmers free-of-charge. This policy is usually implemented through the provincial state<br />

enterprises that supply agricultural inputs. For example, in Ha Giang the Provincial Input Supply<br />

Company buys new varieties of seed <strong>and</strong> sells it to farmers at a subsidized price. Poor households are<br />

supposed to receive a 70 percent subsidy, while others receive a 30 percent subsidy. Households in<br />

communes identified as poor by Program 135 are entitled to receive 5 kg of seed <strong>and</strong> 20 kg of<br />

fertilizer at no cost. In Bac Giang, seed subsdies are available for rice, maize, peanuts, <strong>and</strong> pineapple.<br />

In Yen Bai, the Van Huong Coffee Company offers coffee seedlings <strong>and</strong> fertilizer on credit, with the<br />

cost to be deducted from the crop revenue payments when the trees begin to produce. Bac Kan<br />

province has a subsidy policy on transport for all types of crop seeds. Prior to the planting season,<br />

households make production plans, including planting areas, planned crop verities, <strong>and</strong> so on. Based<br />

on these plans, commune, district <strong>and</strong> province authorities work together to supply the needed inputs<br />

at the fixed price.<br />

Box 6-1. Input subsidies in Lai Chau<br />

In Lai Chau province, in order to implement a policy on input subsidies, the province classifies regions to<br />

identify suitable scope <strong>and</strong> support level among regions. For example, for zone 1, seed support level is 50%, for<br />

zone 2, it is 70% <strong>and</strong> zone 3, it is 90-100%. In addition to this policy, there is a separate policy on support for<br />

crops damaged by natural calamities.<br />

To develop tea in Phong Tho, the Lai Chau Provincial People Committee approved a plan to fund<br />

supplementary support to agricultural production in 2001 (Decision No. 1382/QD-UB, January 1, 2001). Total<br />

support was VND 224 million, subsidizing 50 percent of the cost of tea seedlings to plant in 2001. With<br />

Decision No. 161/QD-UB dated 08/03/2001, the Lai Chau provincial people committee began supporting coffee<br />

planting by households that had suffered damage from natural calamities. The support level is 100% of value of<br />

coffee seedlings for those who have to replant, 100% of interest rate for loans borrowed from banks, lenghtened<br />

repayment terms of more than one year for loans invested in coffee plantation which were damaged by frost.<br />

Transport subsidies. In Bac Kan <strong>and</strong> Lai Chau, officials cited subsidies on transportation<br />

costs to encourage farmers to try new crops. Remote districts also qualify for subsidized<br />

transportation of fertilizer from Hanoi. The goal of this policy is to ensure that farmers in remote<br />

locations are able to buy fertilizer at prices equal to (or at least closer to) the price paid by lowl<strong>and</strong><br />

farmers near Hanoi. The subsidy is only available on fertilizer supplied by state-owned input<br />

companies, so they are often the only supplier in remote areas.<br />

Low-interest loans. Various government programs are used to provide low-interest loans to<br />

farmers to adopt new crops, particularly fruit trees, tea, <strong>and</strong> coffee, which require 3-5 years before the<br />

first harvest. For example, Ha Giang provides VND 1 million in credit for three years for each<br />

hectare of tea planted. Growers of flax receive two-year loans equivalent to 1 ton of maize per<br />

hectare of flax planted. Similarly, officials in Yen Bai noted that funds from the Resettlement<br />

Program <strong>and</strong> Program 327 are used to promote new crops, particularly tree crops<br />

Technical assistance. Most programs to promote a new crop involve technical assistance<br />

from agricultural extension officers. Typically, one or more extension agents will be assigned to<br />

Page 140


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

focus on a crop being promoted in a specific area. For example, in Son La technical assistance <strong>and</strong><br />

budget support are used to promote the expansion of sugarcane area.<br />

Box 6-2. Examples of extension activities<br />

The extension unit of Cho Moi district (Bac Kan) has 14 agents that are based in different communes. They are<br />

supposed to help communes prepare the annually production plan <strong>and</strong> monitor it, as well as introduce new<br />

production techniques. In fact, the main activity of most of them is to provide technical training at the<br />

beginning of the crop season.<br />

In Yen Chau (Son La), the extension unit was established in 1994 <strong>and</strong> has 11 agents. Each of them will be in<br />

charge of one particular program. The goal is to make them more responsible <strong>and</strong> work independently. Most<br />

of them just work with the head of the commune or village. Direct assistance to farmers is limited.<br />

In 2001, the Lai Chau agricultural <strong>and</strong> forestry extension center organized 82 technical training courses for total<br />

4100 farm households. Of these, there were 25 courses on food crop production, 15 courses on industrial <strong>and</strong><br />

fruit trees; 15 courses on forestry extension; 27 courses on livestock <strong>and</strong> fishery.<br />

.<br />

L<strong>and</strong> allocation policy The 1993 L<strong>and</strong> Law (Decree 64/CP) initiated the process of<br />

distributing l<strong>and</strong>-use certificates (LUCs) to farming households. The distribution of l<strong>and</strong>-use<br />

certificates for lowl<strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> is almost complete, but the distribution of LUC’s for upl<strong>and</strong> areas has<br />

been much slower. This is partly due to the fact that upl<strong>and</strong> areas had less clearly defined user rights<br />

than lowl<strong>and</strong> areas <strong>and</strong> partly because the allocation of LUC’s is complicated by the goal of<br />

protecting existing forest l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> stimulating reforestation. Some have expressed concern about the<br />

social impact of the l<strong>and</strong> distribution. There is a widespread impression that the gap between<br />

small <strong>and</strong> large farms is widening.<br />

L<strong>and</strong> allocations in Thai Nguyen <strong>and</strong> Bac Kan are based on the historical distribution of l<strong>and</strong><br />

rather than the numbers of family member. This led to a situation in which some households have<br />

more l<strong>and</strong> than their family labor can farm, while others have too little. In Son La, the system of<br />

allocating agricultural l<strong>and</strong> is slightly different. Here, there is not much irrigated l<strong>and</strong>. Most of the<br />

fields there are upl<strong>and</strong>s, formerly cultivated using slash-<strong>and</strong>-burn methods. If the plot lies in the areas<br />

planned for reforestation, it will be taken back to the State. If not, it will be divided among local<br />

households based on the numbers of people in the family. In Lai Chau, l<strong>and</strong> allocation was only<br />

implemented with the irrigated fields. People in Dien Bien Dong <strong>and</strong> Muong Lay Districts are still<br />

cultivating in their l<strong>and</strong> without any l<strong>and</strong>-use certificates.<br />

L<strong>and</strong> use policy The General Department of L<strong>and</strong> Administration has responsibility for l<strong>and</strong><br />

use planning, with technical assistance from the National Institute for Agricultural Planning <strong>and</strong><br />

Projection (NIAPP). Campaigns to promote new crops may begin with a new l<strong>and</strong> use plan for the<br />

district or province. During most of the 1990s, l<strong>and</strong>-use restrictions made it difficult for farmers to<br />

convert ricel<strong>and</strong> to other crops. As it became clear that Vietnam could reliably produce a surplus in<br />

rice <strong>and</strong> in response to the falling international price of rice in the late 1990s, central government<br />

policy shifted in favor of diversification from rice into high-value commodities. Local governments<br />

Page 141


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

were given more flexibility in regulating l<strong>and</strong> use, but restrictions still apply in many regions.<br />

Officials in Bac Giang listed various policies to promote new crops including a policy to allow<br />

farmers to convert some agricultural l<strong>and</strong> into fruit. Generally, agricultural credit is only available for<br />

investments that are compatible with the l<strong>and</strong>-use plan for the area.<br />

Marketing assistance. There is a general recognition that high-value crops often face serious<br />

marketing problems due to high quality requirements, perishability, <strong>and</strong> instable prices. Some<br />

provinces attempt to stabilize the price by creating state-owned processing-export companies to buy<br />

the output. In Bac Giang, a provincial processing company sign contracts with pineapple farmers,<br />

offering a fixed price in order to ensure adequate supply for the plant. In Yen Bai, the province has<br />

established 4-5 tea processing plants. These efforts may reduce intra-annual price fluctuations, but<br />

they cannot prevent shifts in dem<strong>and</strong> or export competitiveness than will affect domestic prices.<br />

Indeed, officials in Yen Bai report that farmers are puzzled <strong>and</strong> dissatisfied with the tea market<br />

because prices have been so volatile. Officials in Bac Giang were the only ones to mention training<br />

<strong>and</strong> workshops on marketing <strong>and</strong> processing. Most of the provinces visited as part of the QSAID<br />

were not actively involved in helping farmers with agricultural marketing, except to the extent of<br />

creating state-owned enterprises to buy <strong>and</strong> process raw materials.<br />

The provincial budget for subsidies <strong>and</strong> assistance in promoting new crops is difficult to pin<br />

down because it involves a number of components. In Bac Kan, an official estimated the cost to be<br />

VND 3-4 billion (US$ 200-266 thous<strong>and</strong>), while Ha Giang estimated the cost of subsidies for rice <strong>and</strong><br />

maize at VND 9 billion (US$ 600 thous<strong>and</strong>). In Bac Giang, the estimated cost of subsidies for<br />

promoting rice, maize, peanut, <strong>and</strong> pineapple production (mostly with seed subsidies) was about VND<br />

17 billion (US$ 1.1 million).<br />

6.4 Role of traders in diversification<br />

Provincial officials were asked if there were any crops that had exp<strong>and</strong>ed significantly<br />

without being promoted by the provincial government. The officials were unanimous in reporting that<br />

there were no cases of crop production exp<strong>and</strong>ing spontaneously. Although it is true that local<br />

officials may not be aware of the efforts of traders <strong>and</strong> others to promote new crops, the QSAID<br />

Household Survey confirms this finding. Farm households were asked to identify the main source of<br />

encouragement or support in their decision to adopt a new crop. Traders were mentioned by less than<br />

4 percent of the respondents. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, about half the respondents cited friends or neighbors.<br />

Thus, informal exchange of information with other farmers <strong>and</strong> simply observing what other farmers<br />

experiences are is an important factor in farmer decisions on whether to adopt a new crop.<br />

Officials were asked whether private traders play a positive or negative role in promoting new<br />

crops. Most officials argued that traders have an important role because they often market the output<br />

of the new crop, buying it from farmers to sell to processors, wholesalers, or consumers. Respondents<br />

noted that traders are able to set the price, while farmers are forced to accept the price offered to them.<br />

Page 142


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

Box 6-3. A trader in Son La<br />

Mr. Nguyen Duc Khue in Thuan Chau district, Son La province has been trading agricultural products since<br />

1981. In the beginning, he did not have enough money, so he just bought agricultural products at home. Some<br />

years later, after he had gained more confidence, he borrowed from the bank to buy a truck. Having a truck, he<br />

exp<strong>and</strong>ed the business network to the whole village <strong>and</strong> even goes to Dien Bien town to buy rice.<br />

After the harvest, he buys rice from the lowl<strong>and</strong> to sell in Son La. It is not difficult to buy rice from the<br />

lowl<strong>and</strong>s: he just calls the wholesaler <strong>and</strong> informs him/her details of order. In addition, he also provides rice <strong>and</strong><br />

maize milling services. He has never encouraged or helped farmers to plant any new plant species, however he<br />

sometime lets buyers pay later if they have difficulty paying him immediately.<br />

He does not face any difficulties in business with local authorities, though he sometimes finds it difficult to<br />

collect the debts. He loses about VND 2 million annually on average due to bad loans.<br />

6.5 Role of state-owned enterprises<br />

State-owned enterprises play a role in diversification both as suppliers of seed <strong>and</strong> other<br />

inputs <strong>and</strong> as processors of output. As mentioned above, provincial enterprises play an important role<br />

in the distribution of fertilizer <strong>and</strong> seed, particularly in the more remote provinces. The Lai Chau<br />

Agricultural Input Supply Company was cited by officials in that province as playing a key role in<br />

their programs to promote new crops. In Ha Giang as well, officials mentioned the role of the<br />

Provincial Input Supply Company, although private traders also sell fertilizer <strong>and</strong> seed. In Lang Son,<br />

there is also a provincial input supply company, though it tends to focus on the sale of seed for food<br />

crops.<br />

In marketing, a number of the provinces have at least one provincial enterprise involved in<br />

agricultural processing. Unlike in the case of input supply companies, provincial processing<br />

companies appear to be more common in the centrally-located provinces. In Son La, there is a<br />

provincial enterprise that buys maize to produces animal feed. In Ha Giang, one provincial company,<br />

the Bac Quang Food Company, produces wine from plums, while another, the Viet Lam Tea <strong>and</strong><br />

Coffee Company, processes tea. Bac Giang has several provincial processors including an<br />

agricultural export-import company <strong>and</strong> six animal feed processing plants. In Lang Son, provincial<br />

companies are involved in producing bamboo flooring <strong>and</strong> making wrapping paper, but neither<br />

company is financially stable. To the knowledge of our respondents, none of the provincial<br />

enterprises is undergoing any restructuring or equitization under the state enterprise reform program.<br />

Page 143


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

Box 6-4. Agro-processing in Lai Chau<br />

To develop tea production, the Lai Chau has invested in two processing plants with a capacity of 500kg/day<br />

operated by the agricultural breeding company in Tua Chua district. The policy of purchasing fresh bud tea at<br />

VND 2,500/kg has helped to mobilize fresh bud tea from all the district <strong>and</strong> created income for the H'mong<br />

people in upl<strong>and</strong> areas in Tua Chua.<br />

Regarding coffee, the Lai Chau People's Committee issued Decision No. 1368/QD-UB dated 28/9/2001,<br />

approving a purchasing price <strong>and</strong> options to support coffee assembly <strong>and</strong> processing in Lai Chau in order to<br />

market coffee for farmers. The goal is to stabilize coffee price in the face of the rapidly falling international<br />

price.<br />

6.6 Perceived constraints on diversification<br />

Provincial, district, <strong>and</strong> commune officials were asked what constraints prevent farmers in the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s from diversifying into higher-value crops <strong>and</strong> activities. The following is a<br />

summary of these discussions.<br />

6.6.1 Unfavorable production conditions<br />

The production conditions in many parts of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s are very difficult. A large<br />

portion of the l<strong>and</strong> area is hilly or mountains, with poor fertile soils <strong>and</strong> steep slopes. Although the<br />

Government has given priority to the development of irrigation systems in these provinces, because of<br />

the uneven topography <strong>and</strong> fragmented cultivated areas, the irrigation systems are mainly on a small<br />

scale, with limited capacity. A majority of cultivated l<strong>and</strong> areas rely on rain, affecting production<br />

potential <strong>and</strong> limiting improvements in the living st<strong>and</strong>ard. Water is becoming an increasingly serious<br />

issue, both for irrigation <strong>and</strong> for human consumption.<br />

6.6.2 Low level of education <strong>and</strong> training<br />

The level of education of upl<strong>and</strong> farmers is low, particularly in the more remote areas <strong>and</strong><br />

particularly among ethnic minorities. According to the QSAID Household Survey, the average head<br />

of household had just six years of education, <strong>and</strong> less than 20 percent had more than seven years. The<br />

education levels are even lower among households in the more isolated provinces such as Lai Chau.<br />

Furthermore, lack of language skills often makes it more difficult to learn new methods.<br />

Many villagers, especially women of working age, do not know Vietnamese. Thus, the improvement<br />

of technical knowledge <strong>and</strong> production organization skills is made more difficult.<br />

6.6.3 Population pressure on l<strong>and</strong> resources<br />

Terrace-based farming is common modes in northern mountainous provinces. In general, the<br />

amount of cultivated l<strong>and</strong> area depends on the food dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the labour capacity of households.<br />

Local officials argue that farmers do not pay enough attention to soil protection <strong>and</strong> improvement.<br />

Traditionally, farmers would leave the l<strong>and</strong> fallow for 8-10 years. In recent years, the implementation<br />

of l<strong>and</strong> allocation policy <strong>and</strong> high population growth rate have led to intensification of production,<br />

which leads to shorter fallow period (3-4 years) . Cultivation of steep slopes leads to erosion <strong>and</strong> soil<br />

Page 144


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

loss. These problems are not only affecting cultivating capacity in the next l<strong>and</strong>-use cycle, but also the<br />

environment, since after cultivation terraces lose restoration capacity <strong>and</strong> become barren l<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

6.6.4 Lack of credit<br />

Many households <strong>and</strong> some local official argue that that one of the main constraints in<br />

production is the lack of capital. Other information suggests that this issue may be overstated. The<br />

results of the QSAID showed that it is common to see households with access to credit, but who do<br />

not use it productively for various reasons. The Chieng Bom commune (Son La province) is one of<br />

the poorest ones visited. Interviews with local officials revealed that there are 411 poor households in<br />

the commune that had received loans with total amount of VND 602 million. Currently, 30% of these<br />

households have not repaid the loan <strong>and</strong> are not expected to be able to. The amount of unrepaid loans<br />

over the last two years is VND 38 million. The main reasons for the non-repayment, according to<br />

commune officials, is that farmers did not use all the money for the purposed stated in the loan<br />

application, but rather spent the money on more immediate consumption needs. In some cases, social<br />

events such as marriages <strong>and</strong> funerals require significant spending. For example, Ha Van Duy, a Tay<br />

ethnic man in Bac Kan, is the head of a household with medium economic status. For his mother’s<br />

funeral in 1999, he had to purchase 200 kg of pork <strong>and</strong> spent over VND 1.0 million. It took him<br />

almost three years of pig production to pay off the debt.<br />

6.6.5 Poor infrastructure<br />

The lack of infrastructure, particularly roads, was frequently mentioned as a constraint on<br />

diversification. Apart from national roads, which are generally usable in all seasons, the internal road<br />

system is often not usable during the rainy season. The transportation system within communes is<br />

minimal, often suitable only for walking. For example, to reach the Thuong Quan commune (Bac<br />

Kan), it takes a full day of walking.<br />

In recent years, the government has implemented Program 135 to invest in poor <strong>and</strong> remote<br />

communes, but the size of the fund is small relative to the large investment needs of these communes.<br />

As a result, improvements in road infrastructure are slow.<br />

6.6.6 Inappropriate development projects<br />

The development of the production capacity of rural villages has relied heavily on direction<br />

from local authorities. In many places, due to impatience in the economic development toward<br />

industrialization, funds have not been used effectively. For example, in Son La province, many<br />

households need to buy new pig <strong>and</strong> poultry breeds to develop livestock, but there are no breeding<br />

stations available. Villagers have to travel to other provinces like Ha Tay <strong>and</strong> Hung Yen to buy<br />

breeding animals. Another example is sugarcane development. Sugar prices are supported by tight<br />

import quotas on refined sugar, while decisions regarding the establishment of new sugar refineries<br />

has has sometimes followed political <strong>and</strong> development criteria at the expense of agro-climatic<br />

Page 145


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

suitability. As a result, some sugar processing plants are still losing money after four years of<br />

establishment, kept running only with direct subsidies or indirect subsidies through credit from the<br />

banking system.<br />

6.6.7 Lack of information needed for production process<br />

Market information plays an important role in decisions regarding agricultural investments,<br />

planting decisions, <strong>and</strong> use of inputs. However, most of households in the four surveyed provinces<br />

have conducted their activities on production <strong>and</strong> trade with little or no access to information about<br />

market conditions. Consequently, some argue that villagers do not know whether the selling prices<br />

of their products are fair or not, how is their production prospect, how is their trade, <strong>and</strong> so on. It<br />

should be noted that, according to the QSAID Household Survey, many households believe that the<br />

prices they receive are reasonably fair, but they may be wrong.<br />

In addition to the lack of market information, farmers often do not have good information on<br />

the production characteristics of new crops, including the growth rate, life cycle, disease/pest<br />

problems, methods of treatment, <strong>and</strong> so on. Farmers may not be knowledgeable about their soil<br />

characteristics <strong>and</strong> the requirements of different crops, leaving them without much information on<br />

which crops would be suitable for their farms.<br />

6.6.8 Marketing problems<br />

Agricultural marketing involves coordination between farmers <strong>and</strong> buyers, particularly when<br />

the buyer is a processor. In the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, other than staple food crops (paddy, maize, <strong>and</strong><br />

cassava), the quantities marketed of each agricultural commodity are often small. Given the small<br />

quantities, it is difficult to justify investment in agricultural processing facilities. And without the<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> created by processing facilities, there may be little incentive for farmers to produce<br />

significant marketed surpluses. From the point of view of the processor (often a provinciallymanaged<br />

state-owned enterprise), the problem is how to ensure that the availability of raw materials<br />

will be sufficient at prices that allow a profit before the plant is constructed. The development of fruit<br />

trees is an example. Four years ago, one kilogram of plums in Son La sold for VND 2,500; in 2002,<br />

the price of plums was just VND 200 per kg, barely enough for the labor cost of harvesting. As a<br />

result, many households did not bother to harvest their plums. In the QSAID Household Survey,<br />

plums were one of the most commonly cited unsuccessful new crops. Furthermore, it is difficult for<br />

rice grown in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s provinces to compete with that produced in Red River Delta.<br />

Only maize is easy to sell, due to the high dem<strong>and</strong> for animal feed.<br />

Page 146


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

Box 6-5. Marketing problems in Son La<br />

Mr. Ha Van Binh, chairman of Chieng Bom commune (Son La) said “There are three main agricultural<br />

products that farmers sell: cassava, rice <strong>and</strong> maize. The quantities are not large. When farmers want to sell<br />

their products, they have to bring them to district market or mill paddy <strong>and</strong> retail to consumers. Traders<br />

don’t go to village to assemble agricultural products partly because of the bad roads <strong>and</strong> also because the<br />

quantity is often small”. The poverty rate of the commune now is more than 70%. The income from selling<br />

agricultural products is only enough to buy fish source, salt, <strong>and</strong> oil.<br />

6.6.9 Weak extension service<br />

The extension service is one of the main avenues for providing information to farmers<br />

regarding the opportunities for crop diversification, but the extension services suffers from some<br />

systemic weaknesses. Problems identified during the field interviews included the following:<br />

• The number of extension workers is small, with just only one per commune. The size of<br />

the communes in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s is sometimes large due to the sparse population<br />

density. The agents must cover all the activities of agricultural extension in addition to<br />

some related to off-farm activities, reducing its effectiveness.<br />

• The low education level of agents is also an issue. Most of them have been finished high<br />

school only. In some localities such as Xa Ho Commune (Yen Bai) <strong>and</strong> Van Chai<br />

Commune (Ha Giang), extension workers have not finished secondary school.<br />

• The extension workers at commune level are under short contract system of working (36<br />

months) with very low salary (150,000-2000,000 VND/month) without any other<br />

supports. With this level of salary <strong>and</strong> these kinds of works they can not fulfill their tasks<br />

because they have to think about their life <strong>and</strong> their families.<br />

6.7 Summary<br />

The Qualitative Social Assessment of <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> (QSAID) involved interviews<br />

with local authorities in eight provinces, 16 districts, <strong>and</strong> 16 communes in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. The<br />

interviews covered various topics including the types of diversification being undertaken, the policies<br />

being implemented to support diversification, <strong>and</strong> the perceived constraints at the farm level.<br />

The types of diversification vary by province. Most provinces cited diversification into fruit<br />

<strong>and</strong> tea, with a wide range of new crops were mentioned by local officials including anise, cinnamon,<br />

cardamom, sugarcane, coffee, bamboo, flax, tobacco, <strong>and</strong> soybeans. Farmers are also adopting new<br />

varieties of rice <strong>and</strong> hybrid maize in much of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. Local officials report that there is<br />

little diversification into livestock <strong>and</strong> non-farm enterprises, though it is possible that they are less<br />

aware of these trends because they occur with less government support.<br />

Some diversification is occurring in most districts of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, but the pace of<br />

diversification is greater in areas with good market access. Furthermore, the type of diversification<br />

depends on the degree of market access. In provinces close to Hanoi <strong>and</strong> the delta, farmers are<br />

diversifying into litchi, longan, <strong>and</strong> other fruit crops. Farther out, farmers are diversifying into tea,<br />

Page 147


Chapter 6. <strong>Diversification</strong> from the perspective of local government<br />

sugarcane, <strong>and</strong> tobacco. And in the most remote provinces, any diversification that occurs tends to be<br />

into maize or cattle production.<br />

Local authorities are quite active in identifying <strong>and</strong> promoting promising new crops. They<br />

use various policy tools to encourage the adoption of new varieties including input subsidies,<br />

transportation subsidies, technical assistance, low-interest loans, l<strong>and</strong> allocation policy, l<strong>and</strong> use<br />

restrictions, <strong>and</strong> (less often) marketing assistance. Traders seem not to be very involved in promoting<br />

new crops, according to interviews with local officials (this is confirmed by the QSAID Household<br />

Survey).<br />

Constraints to diversification include unfavorable production conditions, the low level of<br />

education <strong>and</strong> training of farmers, population pressure on l<strong>and</strong> resources, lack of credit, <strong>and</strong> poor<br />

infrastructure. Inappropriate development projects, lack of markets, <strong>and</strong> weak extension services<br />

were also mentioned.<br />

Page 148


CHAPTER SEVEN<br />

A SOCIAL ACCOUNTING ANALYSIS OF<br />

ECONOMIC LINKAGES AND DIVERSIFICATION<br />

7.1 Introduction<br />

Successful economic diversification depends upon the income potential of alternative<br />

production activities for households, which in turn depends ultimately on the downstream linkages of<br />

these activities to the rest of the regional, national, <strong>and</strong> global economy. Some activities may be<br />

profitable in some areas, where linkages are well articulated, <strong>and</strong> fail in others that lack appropriate<br />

connections to downstream activities <strong>and</strong> markets. For this reason, elucidating linkages can do much<br />

to improve the quality of diversification decisions <strong>and</strong> increase the ultimate returns to factors<br />

allocated to diversified activities.<br />

One of the most widely used tools for analyzing economic linkages is the Social Accounting<br />

Matrix (SAM), a double entry book keeping device that details bilateral transactions across a region,<br />

nation, or global economy, at any level of detail for which data are available. In the case of Vietnam,<br />

we are fortunate to have a recent national SAM (2000) which was estimated at an exceptionally<br />

detailed level. In this report, we use this SAM <strong>and</strong> other data to produce several new datasets,<br />

including macro SAMs for each of the fourteen provinces in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, a regional SAM<br />

with disaggregation comparable to the national table, <strong>and</strong> finally a singly two-region (Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s-ROV) table which clearly delineates direct <strong>and</strong> indirect income-expenditure linkages within<br />

<strong>and</strong> between the two regions <strong>and</strong> with respect to the rest of the world. All these tabular datasets can<br />

provide new insights about income determination <strong>and</strong> distribution in the region.<br />

The tables produced as part of this project are unprecedented data resources for Vietnam, <strong>and</strong><br />

making them available will stimulate <strong>and</strong> sustain new research on the region for at least 5-10 years. In<br />

addition to developing <strong>and</strong> disseminating new data resources, however, the present study is intended<br />

to provide direct analysis <strong>and</strong> policy guidance. We begin this chapter with an overview of how the<br />

tables were estimated, <strong>and</strong> then follow this with discursive analysis <strong>and</strong> examples of detailed<br />

analytical applications.<br />

7.2 SAM Analysis<br />

7.2.1 Overview<br />

The direct impact of income diversification can be studied quantitatively with survey data <strong>and</strong><br />

qualitatively with focus groups. However, at least as important as the direct impact of income<br />

diversification on participating households are the indirect (or multiplier) effects. These effects can<br />

occur through three channels: backward production linkages, forward production linkages, <strong>and</strong><br />

consumption linkages.<br />

Page 149


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

• Backward production linkages refer to the effect of income diversification on the dem<strong>and</strong><br />

for inputs into the production activity, particularly locally-produced inputs. For example,<br />

the growth of a fishery industry may result in additional dem<strong>and</strong> for locally produced fish<br />

food, fingerlings, pond construction services, <strong>and</strong> so on.<br />

• Forward production linkages refer to the effect of income diversification on downstream<br />

users. For example, the same fishery industry development may lead to new fish drying<br />

enterprises, generating income for employees <strong>and</strong> owners.<br />

• Consumption linkages refer to the impact of diversification on household income <strong>and</strong>,<br />

indirectly, on dem<strong>and</strong> for other goods. For example, households whose incomes have<br />

been increased by aquaculture may increase their purchases of meat, fruits, <strong>and</strong><br />

vegetables, with indirect effects on producers of these commodities.<br />

In order to study these linkages, the project has constructed a social accounting matrix (SAM)<br />

that represents the economy of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, as well as 16 other supporting tables of<br />

complementary <strong>and</strong> independent interest. The Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s SAM is adapted from a national<br />

SAM constructed by two of the international consultants <strong>and</strong> two of the local consultants included in<br />

this project (see Tarp et al, 2001, Tarp et al, 2002a, Tarp et al, 2002b, <strong>and</strong> Tarp <strong>and</strong> Rol<strong>and</strong>-Holst,<br />

2002). This SAM was calibrated to represent the Vietnamese economy in 2000 <strong>and</strong> has a relatively<br />

large number of agricultural commodities <strong>and</strong> services represented in it.<br />

This chapter discusses the estimation procedure used for three types of social accounting<br />

matrices:<br />

• Macroeconomic SAMs for each of the 14 provinces in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the<br />

region as a whole<br />

• A detailed microeconomic SAM for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

• A two region SAM delineating transactions within <strong>and</strong> between the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong><br />

the rest of Vietnam (ROV).<br />

The estimation of the Macro SAMs for the 14 provinces are discussed in section 7.2.2, the<br />

estimation of the Micro SAM for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s in section 7.2.4, <strong>and</strong> the Two-Region SAM in<br />

section 7.4.1.<br />

7.2.2 Estimation of the Macro SAMs for the 14 provinces<br />

In this section, we show how the Macro SAMs for 14 Vietnamese provinces in the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s were developed. The macro-table is essentially a double entry representation of the usual<br />

macroeconomic accounting identities. It is used to ensure that the more detailed activity, commodity,<br />

factor, <strong>and</strong> other institutional accounts in the disaggregated SAM are consistent with existing<br />

Page 150


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

macroeconomic information. Table 7-1 depicts a generic Macro SAM in terms of the st<strong>and</strong>ard macro<br />

accounting identities. Note that in this case intermediate goods are netted out. 1<br />

With these macro accounts in mind, consider the tableau with generic Macro SAM accounts<br />

for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, given in Table 7-2. Intermediate goods are included explicitly, <strong>and</strong><br />

production is decomposed in the activity <strong>and</strong> commodity accounts. While there is a little more detail<br />

in this table, it continues to represent a double entry accounting version of the traditional macro<br />

accounts. Relying on the data supplied by the General Statistics Office (GSO, 2002) <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Vietnamese Macro SAM developed by Tarp et. al. (2002), 14 regional Macro SAMs for northern<br />

Vietnam were developed. The regions covered include: Ha Giang, Cao Bang, Lao Cai, Bac Kan, Lang<br />

Son, Tuyen Quang, Yen Bai, Thai Nguyen, Phu Tho, Bac Giang, Quang Ninh, Lai Chau, Son La <strong>and</strong><br />

Hoa Binh.<br />

This section refers to detailed estimates in Annex E, Tables A7.1-7.15. Values (in millions of<br />

VND at prices of 2000) have been assigned to all of the cells in Table 7.2 for which a transaction<br />

between two accounts took place <strong>and</strong> for which data were available from the GSO or other sources.<br />

Detailed notes on data sources, assumptions, <strong>and</strong> procedures are also outlined in Annex E.<br />

Throughout, the relevant cell in Table 7.2 is referred to as (i, j) where i refers to the row <strong>and</strong> j to the<br />

column.<br />

This Section documents the steps involved in constructing the 14 regional Macro SAMs for<br />

Vietnam, <strong>and</strong> in what follows, reference is made to the individual cells in Table 7-2. The Macro SAM<br />

has nine rows <strong>and</strong> nine columns. Corresponding rows <strong>and</strong> columns share the same label. For example,<br />

row three <strong>and</strong> column three are both labeled “factors”. In the Macro SAM, entries are in the form of<br />

macroeconomic aggregates, <strong>and</strong> the row/column labels are defined below.<br />

In a social accounting matrix (SAM), rows track receipts, while columns track expenditures.<br />

Hence, row <strong>and</strong> column sums represent, respectively, total receipts <strong>and</strong> total payments by a given<br />

account/institution. In the tradition of double entry accounting, row sums must equal column sums.<br />

1 See Reinert <strong>and</strong> Rol<strong>and</strong>-Holst (1997) for a more extensive introduction to Macro SAMs <strong>and</strong> SAM<br />

estimation.<br />

Page 151


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

Table 7-1. An Open-Economy Macro SAM with a Government Sector<br />

Expenditures<br />

Receipts 1 2 3 4 5 Total<br />

1. Suppliers - C G I E Dem<strong>and</strong><br />

2. Households Y - - - - <strong>Income</strong><br />

3. Government - T - - - Receipts<br />

4. Capital Accnt. - S h S g - S f Savings<br />

5. Rest of World M - - - - Imports<br />

Total Supply Expenditure Expenditure Investment ROW<br />

Additional Variables:<br />

t 42 = S h = private savings<br />

t 32 = T = tax payments<br />

t 43 = S g = government savings<br />

t 15 = E = exports<br />

t 45 = S f = foreign savings<br />

t 51 = M = imports<br />

t 13 = G = government spending<br />

Accounting Identities:<br />

1. Y + M = C + G + I + E (GNP)<br />

2. C + T + S h = Y (<strong>Income</strong>)<br />

3. G + S g = T (Govt. Budget)<br />

4. I = S h + S g + S f (Saving-Investment)<br />

5. E + S f = M (Trade Balance)<br />

Page 152


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

Table 7-2. A MacroSAM for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> Region - Generic Macro Accounts<br />

Expenditures<br />

Receipts 1.<br />

Activities<br />

(97)<br />

2.<br />

Commodities<br />

(97)<br />

3.<br />

Factors<br />

(14)<br />

4.<br />

Private<br />

Households<br />

(16)<br />

5.<br />

Enterprises<br />

(3)<br />

6.<br />

Recurrent<br />

State<br />

(1)<br />

7.<br />

Invest<br />

-ment<br />

Savin<br />

gs<br />

(1)<br />

8.<br />

Rest of<br />

World<br />

(94+1)<br />

9.<br />

Total<br />

1.<br />

Activities<br />

(97)<br />

Marketed<br />

Production<br />

Total<br />

Sales<br />

2.<br />

Commodities<br />

(97)<br />

Intermediate<br />

Consumption<br />

Private<br />

Consumption<br />

State<br />

Consumption<br />

Invest<br />

-ment<br />

Exports<br />

Total<br />

Commod<br />

ity<br />

Dem<strong>and</strong><br />

3.<br />

Factors<br />

(14)<br />

Value<br />

Added<br />

Value<br />

Added<br />

4.<br />

Private<br />

Households<br />

(16)<br />

Wages,<br />

Salaries<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

Other<br />

Benefits<br />

Distributed<br />

Profits<br />

Social<br />

Security <strong>and</strong><br />

Other Current<br />

Transfers to<br />

Households<br />

Net Foreign<br />

Transfers to<br />

Households<br />

Private<br />

Househol<br />

d <strong>Income</strong><br />

5.<br />

Enterprises<br />

(3)<br />

Gross<br />

Profits<br />

Enterprise<br />

subsidies<br />

Net Foreign<br />

Transfers to<br />

Enterprises<br />

Enterpris<br />

e <strong>Income</strong><br />

6.<br />

Recurrent<br />

State<br />

(1)<br />

7.<br />

Investment<br />

Savings<br />

(1)<br />

Value<br />

Added<br />

Taxes<br />

Trade Taxes<br />

Production<br />

Taxes<br />

<strong>Income</strong> Taxes<br />

Household<br />

Savings<br />

Enterprise<br />

<strong>Income</strong><br />

Taxes<br />

Retained<br />

Earnings<br />

State Savings<br />

Net Foreign<br />

Transfers to<br />

State<br />

State<br />

Revenue<br />

Total<br />

Savings<br />

8.<br />

Rest of World<br />

(94+1)<br />

Imports<br />

Enterprise<br />

Remittances<br />

Government<br />

Remittances<br />

Imports<br />

9.<br />

Total<br />

Total<br />

Payments<br />

Total<br />

Commodity<br />

Supply<br />

Total<br />

Factor<br />

Payments<br />

Allocation of<br />

Private<br />

Household<br />

<strong>Income</strong><br />

Total<br />

Enterprise<br />

Expenditure<br />

Allocation of<br />

State Revenue<br />

Total<br />

Invest<br />

-ment<br />

Total<br />

Foreign<br />

Exchange<br />

Page 153


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

7.2.3 Data Resources for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s Vietnam Macro SAM<br />

Data resources have been surveyed around the country in official <strong>and</strong> unofficial media, <strong>and</strong><br />

we also undertook a review of relevant data in the h<strong>and</strong>s of bilaterally <strong>and</strong> multilaterally sponsored<br />

activities. The results pointed to two essential sources, General Statistics Office <strong>and</strong> the 1998<br />

Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey (VLSS). To take full advantage of these resources, we have<br />

retained three local research professionals <strong>and</strong> made a small data acquisition agreement with GSO.<br />

In a particular, GSO has supplied the macro accounting information available for each of the<br />

fourteen provinces in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. This information is essential, but insufficient, to calibrate<br />

the Macro SAM for the region <strong>and</strong> make it consistent with the economy-wide Vietnam Macro SAM.<br />

We have already received this <strong>and</strong> other supporting data, consisting of fourteen spreadsheets of<br />

detailed national income <strong>and</strong> product accounts.<br />

The second primary source of regional data is the VLSS, a detailed household survey for<br />

which there are several thous<strong>and</strong> representative households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. From this<br />

dataset, we have extracted information on income sources, expenditure patterns, <strong>and</strong> savings behavior<br />

in a manner consistent with the detailed (97 commodity) final dem<strong>and</strong> accounts of the national SAM.<br />

This gives us income <strong>and</strong> expenditure information for the region’s rural poor at an unprecedented<br />

level of detail <strong>and</strong> facilitates the linkage analysis carried out below.<br />

We subject the new regional SAM to intensive multiplier decomposition analysis, further<br />

elucidating the direct <strong>and</strong> indirect linkages between the rural sector <strong>and</strong> its urban counterparts in the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> elsewhere in the country.<br />

Page 154


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

Data obtained from GSO for construction of North Upl<strong>and</strong>s SAM<br />

Type of data<br />

Details <strong>and</strong> source<br />

Marketed Production<br />

The gross output number as defined in GSO (2001) page 90 - 94 for the<br />

year 2000.<br />

Intermediate Consumption The intermediate consumption number as defined in GSO (2001) page 90 -<br />

94 for the year 2000.<br />

Private (Household) Final Consumption The private consumption number as defined in GSO (2001) page 134 for<br />

the year 2000.<br />

State (Government) Final Consumption The state consumption number as defined in GSO (2001) page 134 for the<br />

year 2000.<br />

Investment/Gross Capital Formation<br />

The investment number as defined in GSO (2001) page 134 for the year<br />

2000 (i.e. gross fixed capital formation <strong>and</strong> change sin inventories)<br />

Net Commodity Resource Flow<br />

This net flow calculated as residual from a supply/use balance table for<br />

each province<br />

Value Added<br />

The value added number as defined in GSO (2001) page 90 - 94 for the<br />

year 2000.<br />

The compensation of employees number as defined in GSO (2001), page<br />

121 - 127 for the year 2000.<br />

Consumption of Fixed Capital.<br />

The consumption of fixed capital number as defined in GSO (2001), page<br />

121 - 127 for the year 2000<br />

Operating Surplus The operating surplus number as defined in GSO (2001), page 121 - 127<br />

for the year 2000.<br />

Production Taxes<br />

The production tax number as defined in GSO (2001), page 121 - 127 for<br />

the year 2000.<br />

State Savings<br />

The state savings calculated as revenue minus expenditure.<br />

State Expenditure by its Various Components Figure representing the various categories of state expenditure, including<br />

transfers such as the social security payments <strong>and</strong> other current transfers<br />

from the state to households, state to enterprises, <strong>and</strong> state to central<br />

government for the year 2000.<br />

State Revenue by its Various Components State revenue by its various components disaggregated by st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

categories<br />

A version of the actual Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s Macro SAM, conformal to the schematic Macro<br />

SAM described above, is presented in Table 7-3. The complete Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s Macro SAM is<br />

presented in Appendix E, including disaggregated Provincial <strong>and</strong> Central Government Accounts.<br />

Since the data we obtained from GSO <strong>and</strong> elsewhere was disaggregated by province, we actually<br />

estimated Macro SAMs for each of the fourteen provinces in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. These tables are<br />

also presented in Tables A7.3-A7.16 in Appendix E.<br />

Page 155


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

Table 7-3. Macro SAM for the Northern Mountain Region, 2000<br />

Expenditures (Bill. VND)<br />

Receipts<br />

(Bill. VND) 1.<br />

Activities<br />

(97)<br />

2.<br />

Commodities<br />

(97)<br />

3.<br />

Factors<br />

(14)<br />

4.<br />

Private<br />

Households<br />

(16)<br />

5.<br />

Enterprises<br />

(3)<br />

6.<br />

Recurrent<br />

State<br />

(1)<br />

7.<br />

Investment<br />

Savings<br />

(1)<br />

8.<br />

Rest of<br />

World<br />

(94+1)<br />

9.<br />

Total<br />

1.<br />

Activities<br />

(97)<br />

58,776 58,776<br />

2.<br />

Commodities<br />

(97)<br />

25,863 22,472 7,475 7,732 16,286 79,827<br />

3.<br />

Factors<br />

(14)<br />

27,120 27,120<br />

4.<br />

Private<br />

Households<br />

(16)<br />

22,407 383 2,939 2,984 28,712<br />

5.<br />

Enterprises<br />

(3)<br />

4,692 355 843 5,891<br />

6.<br />

Recurrent State<br />

(1)<br />

5,793 3,700 20 1,607 2,236 4,392 186 17,934<br />

7.<br />

Investment<br />

Savings<br />

(1)<br />

4,633 41 395 7,732<br />

8.<br />

Rest of World<br />

(94+1)<br />

17,352 609 2,337 20,298<br />

9.<br />

Total<br />

58,776 79,827 27,120 28,712 5,891 17,934 7,732 20,298<br />

Page 156


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

7.2.4 Estimation of the Microeconomic SAM for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

The microeconomic SAM for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s was estimated at the same level of<br />

disaggregation as the economywide 2000 Vietnam SAM estimated by Tarp et al (2002). This table<br />

includes the following primary institutional groups:<br />

• 97 Activity/Commodity Categories<br />

• 12 Occupational categories of Labor<br />

• Capital as a factor of production<br />

• L<strong>and</strong> as a factor of production<br />

• Natural resources as a factor of production<br />

• 8 Types of households<br />

• Types of enterprises<br />

• Provincial <strong>and</strong> Central government accounts<br />

• A variety of fiscal instruments<br />

• Consolidated capital account<br />

• Trade flows with respect to the Rest of Vietnam <strong>and</strong> Rest of World<br />

To estimate the SAM for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, four types of basic data were used:<br />

• The regional Macroeconomic SAMs<br />

• Detailed microeconomic survey data from the 1997-98 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey<br />

(VLSS), a nationally representative household survey with direct sampling in the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

• Independent data on regional trade flows <strong>and</strong> sectoral activity levels.<br />

• The national SAM for 2000.<br />

The basic estimation procedure consisted of a combination of direct survey <strong>and</strong> non-survey<br />

methods. In particular, all direct survey data were combined in the same layout as the national<br />

microeconomic SAM, <strong>and</strong> used as controls to reconcile imputed compositional values for the<br />

remaining accounts. Imputation was carried out by maximum entropy estimation techniques. 2<br />

2 See, for example, Robinson <strong>and</strong> El-Said (1998, 2000) for discussion of these methods.<br />

Page 157


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

The complete Micro SAM for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s is presented in Appendix E, Table A7.16.<br />

For expository purposes, a 38 sector representative aggregation is provided in Table 7-4. This<br />

aggregation forms the basis of the structural narrative in the next section. Although we aggregate from<br />

97 sectors in the original national <strong>and</strong> Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s Micro SAMs, activities of most relevance to<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s household income determination, 18 original agricultural <strong>and</strong> commercial service<br />

sectors, are maintained in the 38 sector aggregation.<br />

As a service to policy makers <strong>and</strong> the research community, the following tables can be<br />

obtained electronically by writing to data@rdrc.net:<br />

1. Complete Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s Micro SAM (252x252)<br />

2. Structural aggregation of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s Micro SAM (107x107)<br />

3. Macro SAMs for Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s (<strong>and</strong> its 14 constituent provinces)<br />

4. Complete two-region Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s-ROV Micro SAM (199x199)<br />

7.3 Structure of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s economy<br />

Table 7.4 presents a variety of disaggregated economic statistics extracted from the 38 sector<br />

aggregate regional SAM, while Table 7.5 defines the labels used in Table 7.4. 3 As mentioned above,<br />

this is based on the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s Micro SAM.<br />

7.3.1 Supply<br />

In column 1, for example, shares of economy-wide marketed gross output are given for all 38<br />

sectors <strong>and</strong> aggregates representing primary, industry, <strong>and</strong> service activities. One would expect that,<br />

for an economy at Vietnam’s stage of development, most of output is concentrated in primary <strong>and</strong><br />

secondary activities. However, the high level of subsistence agriculture in the Northern Mountain<br />

region means that agriculture is a relatively small share of marketed output <strong>and</strong> GDP. The figure of<br />

17.36% is actually below the national average, because in more market oriented regions agriculture is<br />

an important source of money income. Any casual observer of production activity in the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s would conclude that the region is far from realizing the income potential of its resource<br />

allocations to agricultural activities. This is of particular relevance to more remote areas, where<br />

farming occupies the energies of well over the national average of two-thirds of the population,<br />

because of the large subsistence or non-market component of agricultural output.<br />

There are many indications that Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s agricultural potential, <strong>and</strong> especially its<br />

marketable component, could be exp<strong>and</strong>ed significantly <strong>and</strong> sustainably, but ideally this would be<br />

3 The sectoral classification used in the following tables is based on a distinction among primary,<br />

secondary <strong>and</strong> tertiary sectors that is different from the classification used by the GSO. For example, GSO<br />

classifies Mining as a secondary sector of production together with Industry. Abbreviations used in Table 4 are<br />

the following: X = output, Sd = supply for domestic market, E = exports, C = consumption, I = investment, Dd<br />

= dem<strong>and</strong> for domestically produced products, M = import, VA = value added, LVA = labour value added,<br />

KVA = capital value added, TVA = l<strong>and</strong> value added.<br />

Page 158


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

done in ways that respond to more attractive output prices <strong>and</strong> greater value-added capture. In terms<br />

of the former, this would mean shifting the composition of crops toward higher value varieties. More<br />

domestic food processing capacity could also be developed, independently or in foreign partnership,<br />

<strong>and</strong> preferably located in rural regions where the income gains would be most significant.<br />

More detailed inspection reveals that over half of gross output is in primary <strong>and</strong> light industry<br />

sectors, with the highly capital intensive-type industry accounting for less than 8% of total output.<br />

Primarily because of capital insufficiency, Vietnamese industry generally, <strong>and</strong> Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

industry in particular, is only beginning the path to modernization <strong>and</strong> manufacturing diversification<br />

commensurate with its population size <strong>and</strong> resource base. For this reason, processed food,<br />

construction materials, <strong>and</strong> labor-intensive light industries dominate its secondary sector.<br />

Excluding the construction sector, less than one third of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s’s gross output<br />

takes the form of marketable services. A service sector that is large (in terms of output, employment,<br />

<strong>and</strong> value added) is the hallmark of developed countries. The average in the OECD nations is over 65<br />

percent, but Vietnam is only beginning to develop this component of economic activity. As economic<br />

diversification, incomes <strong>and</strong> rural-urban migration rise over time, however, the share of services in<br />

overall output will grow substantially. 4<br />

The second column of Table 7-4 gives sectoral shares of domestic supply, i.e. domestic output<br />

delivered to the domestic market. Generally, the differences between these <strong>and</strong> the gross output shares<br />

are better understood by reference to Columns 3 <strong>and</strong> 4, which give the corresponding export shares, a<br />

measure of supply-side trade dependence for each sector. Despite its heavy reliance on primary sector<br />

activities, Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s marketable exports are more concentrated in sectors classified as<br />

industrial (one half to two-thirds). The main reason for this is the Textile <strong>and</strong> Apparel sector, which<br />

accounts for a large share of total exports in 2000.<br />

More detailed examination of these shares reveals many opportunities for regional<br />

development, however, especially via agricultural diversification. For example, food <strong>and</strong> non-food<br />

crops, such as rice <strong>and</strong> coffee, have significant export shares already but are generally thought to be<br />

producing well below their long-term output <strong>and</strong> revenue potential. Food processing activities could<br />

also animate more extensive market linkages in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

In manufacturing, even a cursory review of column 3 of Table 7-4 indicates that Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s has not yet captured the export potential of dynamic growth sectors in Vietnam or elsewhere<br />

in ASEAN. These sectors not only leverage external dem<strong>and</strong> for domestic employment <strong>and</strong> capacity<br />

development, but also accelerate modernization <strong>and</strong> confer many growth externalities on the domestic<br />

economy. In other economies of the region, the primary catalysts for development of these sectors<br />

4 Note that Services are well ahead in terms of value added, largely because market factor prices in this<br />

sector are closer to (higher) national norms than other activities.<br />

Page 159


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

were foreign capital <strong>and</strong> sustained state commitments to human capital development via education<br />

<strong>and</strong> labor market liberalization.<br />

A more focused comparison between production for domestic <strong>and</strong> external markets can be<br />

made with the ratios given in the fifth <strong>and</strong> sixth columns of the table. Here the export orientation of<br />

certain sectors, such as cash crops <strong>and</strong> energy, comes into very high relief. Several agricultural<br />

sectors, including rice <strong>and</strong> fishery, are still directing the vast majority of their output to intra-regional<br />

markets, while their export potential at the margin is only beginning to be realized. Given that rice has<br />

a low income elasticity (see Chapter 4), its export potential at the margin of a growing economy is<br />

considerable. Conversely, fishery supply may increasingly be diverted to the domestic market as<br />

Vietnamese per capita incomes rise. In the latter case, export shares will depend heavily on capacity<br />

expansion in aquaculture, since marine fisheries in the region are being exploited near or even beyond<br />

sustainable capacity. Significantly, export ratios for food processing are also very low, indicating that<br />

the export potential of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s agricultural sector, apart from classical cash crops like<br />

coffee <strong>and</strong> rubber, is far from being realized. Unless progress can be made in this area, rural incomes<br />

are unlikely to keep pace with growth of the overall economy.<br />

The challenge facing the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s in an era of globalization can be clearly seen in<br />

the average export ratios for primary <strong>and</strong> industry, which indicate a regional economy with very low<br />

levels of external supply orientation in the growth inducing sectors that have accelerated development<br />

<strong>and</strong> living st<strong>and</strong>ards elsewhere in Asia. Without more external market linkage in a variety of essential<br />

industrial activities, Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s is likely to be a chronic underachiever in the Asian<br />

modernization process. Again the main reasons are inadequate productive diversity, capital<br />

insufficiency, <strong>and</strong> lack of access to technology, but institutional conditions can do much to overcome<br />

this, facilitating commercial <strong>and</strong> multilateral trade partnerships to leverage the region’s rich human<br />

<strong>and</strong> natural resource base.<br />

Service sector export ratios are also very low. While it would be nice to see higher levels in<br />

externally oriented sectors like transportation <strong>and</strong> hotels/restaurants, low service exports are typical of<br />

all but the most advanced economies.<br />

7.3.2 Dem<strong>and</strong><br />

Dem<strong>and</strong> patterns for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s are captured in columns 7-13 of Table 7-4, <strong>and</strong><br />

they reflect characteristics typical of economies at the early stages of development. Average incomes<br />

are quite low, <strong>and</strong> private consumption is concentrated on raw <strong>and</strong> processed food products. This is<br />

not apparent in the SAM, however, because of the very high level of subsistence <strong>and</strong> non-market food<br />

consumption. Thus the marketable household budget is concentrated on secondary <strong>and</strong> tertiary<br />

expenditures. Urban households have recently increased dem<strong>and</strong> for durables, but on a national basis,<br />

Vietnamese households have very limited means for discretionary consumption. Most regional cash<br />

Page 160


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

expenditure is for necessary consumer products, <strong>and</strong> greater spending upon services <strong>and</strong> non-home<br />

food products will only come into play after significant gains in domestic per capita income.<br />

Vietnamese investment patterns in 2000 also reflected those of an agrarian<br />

developing country. About two thirds of capital outlays concentrated in the construction sector.<br />

Energy. Machinery, <strong>and</strong> infrastructural services are the main targets of investment <strong>and</strong> the right one’s<br />

to facilitate market access <strong>and</strong> growth for the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. In order to develop more diversified<br />

production capacity consistent with a modernizing economy, however, one would expect to see<br />

investment dem<strong>and</strong> increasing sharply in most of the non-food industrial activities, particularly those<br />

with higher value added.<br />

Columns 9-13 of Table 7-4 describe dem<strong>and</strong> patterns by origin of goods <strong>and</strong> services<br />

consumed. Here we see significant disparities between domestic <strong>and</strong> imported expenditure shares,<br />

largely a result of the degree of specialization in the regional economy. Most food dem<strong>and</strong> is met by<br />

home production, while fully 85% of foreign imports are manufactured goods for which there is little<br />

or no Vietnamese domestic substitute <strong>and</strong> 50% of ROV imports are manufactures not made in the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. 5 The largest component of domestic Service dem<strong>and</strong> is for a non-tradable,<br />

Commercial Trade.<br />

5 At very detailed customs lines, one observes very little intra-industry trade for Vietnam for the same<br />

reason. This is symptomatic of low levels of domestic product diversification.<br />

Page 161


Table 7.4: Structure of Marketed Supply, Dem<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> Value Added for the Northern Mountain Region of Vietnam, 2000<br />

(all figures in percentages except as indicated)<br />

1 2 3 4 5* 6* 7 8 9 10 11 12* 13* 14 15 16 17 17<br />

X S EV EW EV/S EW/S C I D MV MW MV/D MW/D VA LVA KVA L<strong>and</strong>VA L/KVA<br />

1 Rice 3.30 3.76 1.12 1.11 .05 .02 8.95 1.98 3.50 .03 .03 .00 .00 .85 .58 .85 11.20 1.75<br />

2 Raw Rubber .19 .02 1.02 .91 6.65 1.99 .00 .00 .02 .06 .06 .70 .25 .34 .11 .58 5.11 .50<br />

3 Coffee Bean .47 .00 2.80 2.35 162.20 45.51 .00 .00 .00 .02 .02 .74 .26 .90 .59 .80 14.11 1.88<br />

4 Sugar Cane .31 .38 .00 .00 .00 .00 .10 .00 .03 .00 .00 .00 .00 .82 .90 .06 9.06 39.19<br />

5 Other Crops 1.61 1.69 1.02 1.88 .10 .06 1.99 .07 .99 1.28 1.42 .24 .09 2.83 2.46 .73 47.29 8.69<br />

6 Pigs 1.26 1.37 .74 .73 .09 .03 4.41 .28 1.50 .01 .01 .00 .00 1.03 1.13 .58 3.82 5.02<br />

7 Poultry .32 .36 .15 .15 .07 .02 .93 .01 .30 .02 .02 .01 .01 .64 .83 .05 2.18 45.29<br />

8 Other Livestock .18 .18 .04 .42 .03 .12 .41 .12 .17 .01 .01 .01 .00 .20 .21 .15 .41 3.55<br />

9 Irrigation Services .07 .08 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .09 .09 .09 .00 2.70<br />

10 Other Ag. Services .11 .13 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .15 .16 .15 .00 2.74<br />

11 Foestry .67 .80 .09 .08 .02 .01 .79 .01 .33 .28 .30 .16 .06 1.49 1.79 .40 6.05 11.44<br />

12 Fishery 1.55 1.77 .46 .46 .04 .01 1.00 .01 .35 .09 .10 .05 .02 2.88 3.48 1.48 .79 6.07<br />

13 Energy 6.19 7.11 1.79 1.97 .04 .01 1.03 23.30 15.28 39.15 1.72 .49 .01 1.39 1.68 .76 .00 5.70<br />

14 Mining 1.13 1.32 .23 .23 .03 .01 .00 .00 .13 .58 .29 .86 .14 .84 1.02 .43 .00 6.07<br />

All Primary 17.36 18.98 9.45 10.28 .08 .03 19.61 25.79 22.60 41.53 3.98 .35 .01 14.46 15.02 7.11 100.00 9.91<br />

15 Processed Meat .13 .11 .19 .19 .27 .09 .10 .02 .04 .01 .01 .03 .01 .10 .10 .10 .00 2.71<br />

16 Dairy .15 .15 .13 .13 .14 .04 .09 .10 .13 .24 .29 .36 .15 .04 .03 .08 .00 1.03<br />

17 Fruits <strong>and</strong> Vegetables .34 .34 .34 .34 .16 .05 1.08 .00 .36 .05 .05 .02 .01 .22 .23 .20 .00 3.00<br />

18 Sugar .62 .71 .17 .16 .04 .01 .13 2.07 .79 .35 .37 .08 .03 .38 .17 .95 .00 .47<br />

19 Coffee Beverages .05 .02 .18 .15 1.16 .33 .03 .00 .02 .03 .03 .30 .11 .07 .08 .05 .00 4.28<br />

20 Other Bev <strong>and</strong> Tobacco 10.08 11.90 1.37 1.52 .02 .01 41.13 .43 13.44 .10 2.56 .00 .01 1.64 .96 3.50 .00 .71<br />

21 Seafood 1.76 .35 9.66 4.91 4.34 .73 .40 .00 .14 .03 .03 .04 .01 1.41 1.58 1.08 .00 3.79<br />

22 Animal Feed .39 .48 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .02 .21 .78 .84 .72 .25 .33 .41 .14 .00 7.56<br />

23 Other Proc. Food .99 1.09 .51 .50 .07 .02 2.32 .17 1.16 1.41 1.57 .23 .09 .99 .81 1.52 .00 1.37<br />

24 Building Materials 11.01 5.21 50.18 3.98 1.52 .04 2.92 .94 2.26 3.94 4.42 .33 .12 4.81 2.23 11.81 .00 .49<br />

25 Industrial Chemicals 2.89 3.30 .93 .92 .04 .01 2.42 .85 3.98 11.66 11.60 .55 .18 .49 .45 .66 .00 1.75<br />

26 Ag. Chemicals .63 .73 .19 .19 .04 .01 .00 .05 .44 .75 4.48 .32 .64 .24 .23 .28 .00 2.07<br />

27 Techincal Mfg .33 .40 .00 .00 .00 .00 .18 .66 .69 1.62 1.78 .45 .16 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00<br />

28 Vehicles .79 .96 .00 .00 .00 .00 .86 .69 1.53 4.63 2.57 .57 .11 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00<br />

29 Machinery 3.58 4.30 .14 .14 .01 .00 1.13 10.53 8.05 8.16 44.08 .19 .35 .09 .09 .09 .00 2.43<br />

30 Metal Products 2.51 3.03 .05 .05 .00 .00 .23 .40 2.67 10.99 6.18 .78 .15 .64 .57 .85 .00 1.73<br />

31 Textile <strong>and</strong> Apparel 7.94 5.07 13.89 44.80 .43 .46 4.27 .82 2.19 2.22 2.26 .19 .07 2.96 2.98 3.11 .00 2.47<br />

32 Other Industry 1.68 1.73 1.22 1.98 .11 .06 2.27 .49 1.59 2.61 3.40 .31 .13 1.04 .86 1.57 .00 1.40<br />

All Industry 45.86 39.87 79.16 59.96 .21 .05 59.58 18.24 39.67 49.57 86.53 .32 .07 15.46 11.78 25.99 .00 1.65<br />

33 Utilities 1.50 1.81 .00 .00 .00 .00 1.16 .00 .40 .11 .13 .05 .02 3.08 .94 8.82 .00 .27<br />

34 Construction 5.65 6.84 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 23.21 7.40 .00 .00 .00 .00 10.89 2.17 34.11 .00 .16<br />

35 Commercial Trade 11.96 14.47 .00 .00 .00 .00 13.56 32.47 14.68 .00 .00 .00 .00 25.00 35.37 .00 .00 .00<br />

36 Transport Services 1.75 1.55 2.69 2.66 .27 .09 .63 .27 .80 2.03 2.05 .48 .16 2.81 1.03 7.58 .00 .35<br />

37 Other Private Serv 9.93 9.48 7.53 25.67 .13 .14 5.47 .01 8.36 6.76 7.31 .15 .06 16.99 18.58 14.05 .00 3.40<br />

38 Public Services 6.00 7.00 1.17 1.42 .03 .01 .00 .00 6.09 .00 .00 .00 .00 11.31 15.10 2.34 .00 16.61<br />

All Service 36.78 41.15 11.39 29.76 .04 .04 20.81 55.97 37.73 8.90 9.49 .04 .02 70.09 73.19 66.91 .00 3.56<br />

* Figures in these columns are simple ratios, with group weighted averages.


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

Table 7.5: Key to Labels<br />

No. Variable Definition<br />

1 X Total Sectoral Output<br />

2 S Regional Supply to the Regional Market - Internal or Domestic Supply<br />

3 EV Exports to the Rest of Vietnam<br />

4 EW Exports to the Rest of the World<br />

5 EV/S Ratio of ROV Exports to Domestic Supply<br />

6 EW/S Ratio of ROW Exports to Domestic Supply<br />

7 C Final Household Consumption<br />

8 I Investment<br />

9 D Regional Dem<strong>and</strong> for Regional <strong>and</strong> Imported Products - Domestic Dem<strong>and</strong><br />

10 MV Imports from the Rest of Vietnam<br />

11 MW Imports from the Rest of the World<br />

12 MV/D Ratio of ROV Imports to Domestic Supply<br />

13 MW/D Ratio of ROW Imports to Domestic Supply<br />

14 VA Total Value Added<br />

15 LVA Labor Value Added<br />

16 KVA Capital Value Added<br />

17 L/K Ratio of Labor to Capital Value Added<br />

Factor<br />

HouseHold<br />

1 L01RU Rural Unskilled Labor HH01RF Rural Farmers<br />

2 L02RM Rural Medium Skilled Labor - Includes Farmers HH02RS Rural Self-Employed<br />

3 L03RH Rural High Skilled Labor HH03RW Rural Wage Worker<br />

4 L04UU Urban Unskilled HH04RU Rural Unemployed<br />

5 L05UM Urban Medium Skilled HH05UF Urban Farmers<br />

6 L06UH Urban High Skilled HH06US Urban Self-Employed<br />

7 Capital Capital HH07UW Urban Wage Worker<br />

8 L<strong>and</strong> L<strong>and</strong> HH08UU Urban Unemployed<br />

Page 163


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

Columns 12 <strong>and</strong> 13 of Table 7-4 give ratios of relative import dependence that are analogous<br />

to the export ratios in column 4. These tell a similar story to the observations of the paragraph above,<br />

but more strikingly. These reinforce the impression of Vietnam generally, <strong>and</strong> the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

in particular, as an emergent agrarian economy, still heavily reliant on imported technology <strong>and</strong><br />

vulnerable to shocks in the global terms of trade. In the past, developing countries attempted to reduce<br />

these risks with inward oriented import substitution strategies. Today, it is generally acknowledged<br />

that imports are better displaced by domestic capacity developed from greater participation in external<br />

product <strong>and</strong> capital markets.<br />

7.3.3 Value added<br />

The sectoral information in columns 14-17 of the table lead us into discussion of regional<br />

income determination, detailing value added shares for labor, capital <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> across 38 activities.<br />

Here again we see characteristics typical of an agrarian economy with high levels of microeconomic<br />

food self-sufficiency. Over 80% of total value added arises in primary <strong>and</strong> tertiary activities, with<br />

industry accounting for only 17% (<strong>and</strong> about 10% when food processing is excluded). L<strong>and</strong> value<br />

added is naturally concentrated in the primary sector.<br />

It was observed earlier that OECD countries generate the largest share of value added in<br />

Service activities, but of course this happens only after their transition through an industrial phase,<br />

where manufacturing becomes the dominant source of employment <strong>and</strong> factor income. Vietnamese<br />

services are characterizes by relatively simple distribution activities <strong>and</strong> have neither the technological<br />

sophistication nor the skill-intensity of advanced economy professional services. Thus we can expect<br />

that the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s awaits a three state transition, accompanied by significant rural-urban<br />

demographic change:<br />

1. The present stage, where agriculture <strong>and</strong> petty commerce dominate value added;<br />

2. Industrialization <strong>and</strong> significant new urbanization, driven by exports, <strong>and</strong> technology<br />

transfer;<br />

3. Modernization, with higher domestic incomes <strong>and</strong> a large, diversified internal market<br />

with a dominant, modern service sector.<br />

Looking at value added by factor type, we see again that the apparent allocation of labor to<br />

agriculture in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s is not rewarded by marketable production. Labor value added<br />

instead is concentrated in commercial intermediation, Trade <strong>and</strong> Transport, as well as wage-oriented<br />

light industry. These results make it clear that more marketable economic diversification in Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s agriculture will be essential to increasing regional incomes.<br />

To get a clearer impression of the relative rewards to different factors engaged in different<br />

activities, consider the labor to capital value added ratios in column 17. Here the labor intensity of<br />

Page 164


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

certain activities is very obvious, like Sugar Cane, Poultry, <strong>and</strong> Forestry. By contrast, Processed Food<br />

<strong>and</strong> manufactures are much more capital intensive. Large disparities in factor intensity are also<br />

evident in Services, where Public Services are about 5 times more labor intensive than Private<br />

Services. All these differences imply that the employment <strong>and</strong> distributional implications of industry<br />

policy need careful forethought. Sectors that are targeted for expansion, whether to serve domestic or<br />

external markets can have very different effects on domestic factor use <strong>and</strong> relative incomes, <strong>and</strong><br />

these effects will ultimately have political as well as economic consequences.<br />

7.3.4 Factor income<br />

Patterns of factor ownership <strong>and</strong> relative returns to those factors are of course the primary<br />

determinants of both absolute <strong>and</strong> relative incomes. This is true in a market or comm<strong>and</strong> economy, or<br />

indeed any economy that attempts to combine the two types of organization. While Vietnam is in a<br />

transition to a mixed economy, the labor intensity of most of its production activities means that labor<br />

compensation is the principal determinant of private domestic incomes. Because of its disaggregated<br />

treatment of both the sources of employment <strong>and</strong> occupational categories, the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s SAM<br />

provides very detailed information on the functional distribution of income.<br />

Table 7-6 displays the composition of direct income (value added) accruing to each of six<br />

labor categories, capital, <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong>, represented here as percent shares of one Dong of value added in<br />

each of the 38 sectors (see Table 7-5 for a key to the factor labels). 6 These figures thus sum to one<br />

hundred percent across each row, <strong>and</strong> weighted averages are given for each of the three generic<br />

activity categories: Primary, Industry, <strong>and</strong> Services.<br />

In primary sectors, the majority of value added accrues to unskilled labor, totaling 56.01%<br />

when Rural (column 1) <strong>and</strong> Urban (column 4) workers are combined. Excluding energy <strong>and</strong> mining<br />

sectors, returns to Primary unskilled labor are over two-thirds of total Primary value added. Returns to<br />

capital in Primary activities vary tremendously, from a low of 2 percent in Rice to 47 percent in Raw<br />

Rubber. L<strong>and</strong> is only accounted as a factor in ten primary activities, <strong>and</strong> its share of value added<br />

varies considerably, but in accordance with intuition.<br />

Patterns of ownership in agriculture also differ sharply between subsistence <strong>and</strong> cash crops,<br />

where relative returns to capital in Rubber, Coffee, <strong>and</strong> Pigs are multiples of those in Sugar Cane,<br />

Other (food) Crops, <strong>and</strong> Poultry. This dichotomy reflects two main tendencies. Firstly, low levels of<br />

mechanization exist in basic food production because of capital insufficiency <strong>and</strong> absence of scale<br />

economies. Second, state owned enterprises in the agricultural export sectors have succeeded, but not<br />

substantially transformed, the plantation system in terms of consolidated property ownership,<br />

technology, <strong>and</strong> factor use. One might argue that public ownership of the non-labor factors in this<br />

6 The sectoral classification used in the following tables is based on a distinction among primary,<br />

secondary <strong>and</strong> tertiary sectors that is different from the classification used by the GSO (1999). For example,<br />

GSO classifies Mining as a secondary sector of production together with Industry. Abbreviations used in Table<br />

7-5 follow the labels regarding factor disaggregation used in Appendix E.<br />

Page 165


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

sector resolves the distributional problem. Historically, however, the management model for state<br />

owned enterprises (SOEs) have not been associated with high levels of retained earnings, thus<br />

reducing final income to the owners of capital, be they public or private.<br />

Fishery, by contrast, has developed <strong>and</strong> exp<strong>and</strong>ed its export potential with over 85% of value<br />

added still accruing to labor. Perhaps more appropriate technology choice <strong>and</strong> extension programs<br />

could increase cash crop labor value added <strong>and</strong> external market access for small holders. Smallholder<br />

promotion is an essential component of modern agricultural reform <strong>and</strong> sustainable rural development<br />

strategy.<br />

Value added composition is more homogeneous across industrial sectors in Vietnam, with<br />

average shares for skill categories a little more uniform <strong>and</strong> higher shares for capital (averaging 33<br />

percent). Unskilled labor as a group receives little under half of value added on average. Both Rural<br />

<strong>and</strong> Urban female workers receive larger shares in Industrial than in Primary employment.<br />

Important differences are still readily apparent, particularly in value added accruing to capital.<br />

Nearly half of all value added accrues to capital in the Beverage/Tobacco <strong>and</strong> Manufactured Materials<br />

sectors, <strong>and</strong> this is consistent with high levels of mechanization.<br />

A lower level of capital share in value added is a double-edged sword for economic<br />

modernization in Vietnam. While it is desirable that labor receives significant compensation, returns<br />

to capital are indicators of both the incentive <strong>and</strong> the progress toward higher levels of technology <strong>and</strong>,<br />

ultimately, labor productivity. Most OECD countries passed through periods of high capital value<br />

added shares en route to their current high productivity, high wage status. If Vietnam succeeds in<br />

attracting the capital needed to transform its manufacturing base, it is reasonable to expect that capital<br />

value added shares will rise steadily for a decade or two before falling again. Of course, these relative<br />

gains for capital will be accompanied by absolute increases in labor value added as economic growth<br />

accelerates.<br />

A final point worth noting about the Industry results is the very low share of value added<br />

accruing to Highly Skilled Labor, less than 2 percent for the combined averages of columns 3 <strong>and</strong> 6.<br />

In part this reflects the scarcity of this kind of labor in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, but of course it also<br />

reflects the stage of industrialization <strong>and</strong> capitalization arguments of the preceding paragraph. To<br />

realize its economic potential, Vietnam must more fully realize its human potential. A reformed<br />

market economy can facilitate this process by pairing technology with labor in ways that accelerate<br />

the growth of the skill base, steadily increasing labor productivity <strong>and</strong>, ultimately, wages. For a poor<br />

country with limited means of financing universal higher education, this is an essential consideration<br />

for economic growth policy.<br />

Value added composition within Service sectors is quite diverse, <strong>and</strong> the averages in this<br />

group are not particularly illuminating. This is because services are produced <strong>and</strong> delivered with very<br />

diverse technologies. Electricity, Gas <strong>and</strong> Water <strong>and</strong> Commercial Services both have high capital<br />

shares, but for different reasons. The former is a classical, big machine capital-intensive activity,<br />

Page 166


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

while the latter is small machine, technology intensive. Public Services, by contrast, both give over<br />

90% of value added to labor.<br />

Table 7-7 details the sectoral origins of household income. By using reduced form<br />

calculations on the SAM, it is possible to impute sectoral value added directly to households, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

entries in this table detail this incidence for the representative 38 sector aggregation <strong>and</strong> 6 household<br />

types.<br />

The most arresting feature of these results has already been alluded to, i.e. the very low<br />

relative market income for farm households for their primary crops. Because of the very high level of<br />

subsistence farming in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, particularly in Rice, farmers receive only a small<br />

fraction of their income from these products. More marketable products, like vegetables <strong>and</strong> fruit<br />

(Other Crops), Forestry products, <strong>and</strong> Fishery give them much greater direct income. Ironically, the<br />

largest source of cash income for most household in the region is Services, like an OECD country, but<br />

in this case merely because agriculture is too marginalized into subsistence. Once again, greater crop<br />

diversification, overall agricultural productivity, <strong>and</strong> downstream (i.e. food processing) investment are<br />

all needed to increase the profitability of Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s farming. Also essential are investments in<br />

infrastructure that can improve market access for small holders.<br />

Page 167


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

Table 7.6: Factor <strong>Income</strong> by Source of Employment<br />

(all figures in percentages)<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8<br />

L01RU L02RM L03RH L04UU L05UM L06UH Capital L<strong>and</strong><br />

1 Rice 0.00 29.55 1.09 15.01 2.10 0.16 27.32 24.76<br />

2 Raw Rubber 21.68 1.97 0.22 0.00 0.00 0.00 47.41 28.73<br />

3 Coffee Bean 39.46 6.15 0.21 0.07 0.07 0.00 24.48 29.56<br />

4 Sugar Cane 68.21 6.29 0.12 1.69 0.93 0.00 1.97 20.79<br />

5 Other Crops 32.69 8.38 0.43 18.65 0.95 0.35 7.07 31.48<br />

6 Pigs 50.19 13.94 0.65 9.93 2.15 0.69 15.44 7.01<br />

7 Poultry 69.35 15.48 0.52 4.32 1.60 0.28 2.02 6.43<br />

8 Other Livestock 66.31 5.58 0.06 1.25 1.75 0.05 21.14 3.86<br />

9 Irrigation Services 64.71 7.33 0.00 0.96 0.00 0.00 27.00 0.00<br />

10 Other Ag. Services 61.39 7.91 0.08 3.03 0.86 0.02 26.71 0.00<br />

11 Foestry 31.48 8.57 1.42 33.50 8.62 1.34 7.43 7.65<br />

12 Fishery 31.89 8.60 1.30 33.74 8.64 1.24 14.07 0.52<br />

13 Energy 46.59 13.89 3.37 15.35 5.03 0.86 14.92 0.00<br />

14 Mining 47.38 13.89 3.28 15.44 5.03 0.84 14.15 0.00<br />

All Primary 45.09 10.54 0.91 10.92 2.70 0.42 17.94 11.49<br />

15 Processed Meat 25.97 6.81 1.24 27.74 10.51 0.81 26.92 0.00<br />

16 Dairy 17.64 3.85 0.14 19.76 9.07 0.21 49.33 0.00<br />

17 Fruits <strong>and</strong> Vegetables 26.05 7.88 2.12 27.79 9.37 1.82 24.97 0.00<br />

18 Sugar 11.05 3.39 0.93 11.87 4.00 0.80 67.95 0.00<br />

19 Coffee Beverages 28.68 7.87 1.68 30.51 11.09 1.25 18.92 0.00<br />

20 Other Bev <strong>and</strong> Tobacco 14.32 4.08 0.90 15.68 5.88 0.69 58.46 0.00<br />

21 Seafood 27.61 8.16 2.09 29.41 10.09 1.75 20.89 0.00<br />

22 Animal Feed 41.61 12.53 3.18 22.11 7.61 1.29 11.68 0.00<br />

23 Other Proc. Food 20.56 5.00 0.63 22.16 8.95 0.46 42.25 0.00<br />

24 Building Materials 15.56 4.61 1.15 8.15 2.76 0.47 67.29 0.00<br />

25 Industrial Chemicals 29.88 8.98 2.23 16.03 5.62 0.89 36.36 0.00<br />

26 Ag. Chemicals 32.69 9.26 2.13 16.81 5.71 0.84 32.56 0.00<br />

27 Techincal Mfg 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

28 Vehicles 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

29 Machinery 33.31 10.66 3.62 15.08 6.99 1.21 29.13 0.00<br />

30 Metal Products 30.11 8.93 2.23 15.82 5.39 0.90 36.62 0.00<br />

31 Textile <strong>and</strong> Apparel 12.29 3.82 1.13 36.94 14.42 2.55 28.85 0.00<br />

32 Other Industry 27.67 8.12 1.92 14.71 5.18 0.75 41.65 0.00<br />

All Industry 21.94 6.33 1.52 18.36 6.81 0.93 32.99 0.00<br />

33 Utilities 13.83 4.10 1.09 1.72 0.66 0.10 78.50 0.00<br />

34 Construction 5.27 5.39 1.26 1.57 0.53 0.08 85.90 0.00<br />

35 Commercial Trade 4.57 2.51 0.70 85.60 5.66 0.96 0.00 0.00<br />

36 Transport Services 16.76 4.92 1.39 1.88 0.87 0.09 74.08 0.00<br />

37 Other Private Serv<br />

38 Public Services<br />

55.97<br />

60.65<br />

4.83<br />

6.13<br />

1.43<br />

1.34<br />

10.09<br />

18.80<br />

4.33<br />

6.55<br />

0.65<br />

0.85<br />

22.70<br />

5.68<br />

0.00<br />

0.00<br />

All Service 26.17 4.65 1.20 19.94 3.10 0.46 44.48 0.00<br />

Page 168


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

Table 7.7: Household <strong>Income</strong>s by Source of Economic Activity<br />

(all figures in percentages)<br />

1 2 3 5 6 7<br />

HH01RF HH02RS HH03RW HH05UF HH06US HH07UW<br />

1 Rice .51 2.25 1.12 .58 1.15 1.89<br />

2 Raw Rubber .09 .81 .19 .41 .29 .17<br />

3 Coffee Bean .44 2.43 .61 1.49 .83 .77<br />

4 Sugar Cane .67 1.99 .59 1.87 .63 .81<br />

5 Other Crops 2.30 8.16 2.57 4.15 3.59 3.30<br />

6 Pigs .90 1.68 1.01 1.75 .76 1.42<br />

7 Poultry .62 1.13 .61 1.40 .38 .95<br />

8 Other Livestock .16 .27 .13 .41 .08 .16<br />

9 Irrigation Services .07 .10 .06 .18 .02 .07<br />

10 Other Ag. Services .12 .17 .10 .30 .05 .14<br />

11 Forestry 1.70 2.36 1.97 1.78 2.30 2.20<br />

12 Fishery 3.31 3.28 3.69 3.27 3.93 4.08<br />

13 Energy 1.34 1.78 1.89 2.16 1.38 2.13<br />

14 Mining .81 1.08 1.13 1.31 .83 1.28<br />

All Primary 13.02 27.48 15.68 21.06 16.23 19.39<br />

15 Processed Meat .10 .10 .12 .10 .14 .13<br />

16 Dairy .03 .03 .04 .04 .05 .04<br />

17 Fruits <strong>and</strong> Vegetables .21 .24 .30 .22 .31 .30<br />

18 Sugar .17 .26 .30 .26 .27 .23<br />

19 Coffee Beverages .07 .08 .10 .08 .11 .10<br />

20 Other Bev <strong>and</strong> Tobacco .91 1.22 1.46 1.23 1.47 1.27<br />

21 Seafood 1.45 1.56 1.97 1.47 2.10 2.03<br />

22 Animal Feed .34 .42 .48 .46 .42 .53<br />

23 Other Proc. Food .76 .86 1.00 .88 1.16 1.01<br />

24 Building Materials 1.96 3.38 3.69 3.84 2.81 2.96<br />

25 Industrial Chemicals .38 .50 .57 .56 .48 .58<br />

26 Ag. Chemicals .19 .25 .27 .29 .23 .29<br />

27 Techincal Mfg .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00<br />

28 Vehicles .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00<br />

29 Machinery .07 .10 .12 .11 .10 .12<br />

30 Metal Products .49 .65 .73 .73 .61 .74<br />

31 Textile <strong>and</strong> Apparel 2.98 2.84 4.19 1.91 5.53 4.04<br />

32 Other Industry .73 1.00 1.10 1.12 .93 1.10<br />

All Industry 10.86 13.48 16.42 13.28 16.72 15.47<br />

33 Utilities .76 1.90 1.90 2.37 1.03 1.29<br />

34 Construction 1.52 2.77 3.51 2.15 1.94 4.50<br />

35 Commercial Trade 45.79 19.95 32.32 7.71 39.74 28.61<br />

36 Transport Services .80 1.88 1.89 2.37 1.03 1.40<br />

37 Other Private Serv 14.70 18.67 15.86 30.01 12.15 15.80<br />

38 Public Services 12.55 13.88 12.41 21.05 11.16 13.56<br />

All Service 76.12 59.04 67.90 65.66 67.05 65.15<br />

Page 169


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

7.4 Linkages between the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> other regions<br />

7.4.1 Estimating the two-region Micro SAM<br />

In order to examine linkages between the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the rest of Vietnam, we need<br />

to construct a two-region SAM, capturing transactions within <strong>and</strong> between the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong><br />

the Rest of Vietnam (ROV). To keep things tractable, this table was produced at the 38-sector<br />

aggregation level, based on more detailed Micro SAMs for both regions.<br />

The two region table forms the basis of the regional multiplier decomposition analysis<br />

reported below. After completing estimation of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s SAM, this table was combined<br />

with the 2000 national Vietnam SAM into a two-region SAM. This was done at the 38 sector<br />

aggregation level to keep the analysis tractable, but all primary sectors were preserved from the<br />

original, 97 sector SAMs. To see this process schematically, consider the two individual Micro<br />

SAMs, which can be partitioned as follows<br />

⎡T T X<br />

T T T X<br />

NN NV 13<br />

=<br />

⎢<br />

⎥<br />

⎢ VN VV 23 ⎥<br />

⎢⎣X X X<br />

31 32 33<br />

⎤<br />

⎥⎦<br />

where N denotes the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> V the Rest of Vietnam (ROV). The component<br />

matrices denote intra-regional <strong>and</strong> inter-regional transactions between institutions including<br />

production activities, factors, <strong>and</strong> households. The exogenous accounts (X) denote transactions with<br />

government, capital accounts, <strong>and</strong> the Rest of the World. The table T represents the two-region SAM<br />

that forms the basis of the linkage decomposition analysis. 7<br />

To evaluate economywide multiplier effects <strong>and</strong> linkages to external trade, first<br />

consider the expenditure shares<br />

⎡A A A<br />

A A A A<br />

NN NV 13<br />

=<br />

⎢<br />

⎥<br />

⎢ VN VV 23 ⎥<br />

⎢⎣<br />

A A A<br />

31 32 33<br />

⎤<br />

⎥⎦<br />

<strong>and</strong> define the additive decomposition<br />

A -x = B + C (2.3)<br />

where A -x denotes the sub-matrix of A with only endogenous institutions (activities, factors,<br />

households, <strong>and</strong> enterprises) <strong>and</strong><br />

B =<br />

⎡A<br />

⎢<br />

⎣ 0<br />

NN<br />

A<br />

0<br />

VV<br />

⎤<br />

⎥<br />

⎦<br />

(2.4)<br />

7 This 199x199 table is being made available for dissemination in Excel format as RegSAM.xls.<br />

Page 170


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

C =<br />

⎡ 0<br />

⎢<br />

⎣A<br />

VN<br />

A<br />

NV<br />

0<br />

⎤<br />

⎥<br />

⎦<br />

(2.5)<br />

From accounting identities one then obtains<br />

y = Ay + x<br />

= By + Cy + x<br />

= (I - B) -1 Cy + (I - B) -1 x<br />

= [I - (I - B) -1 C] -1 (I - B) -1 x<br />

= (I - D) -1 (I - B) -1 x<br />

= (I - D 2 ) -1 (I + D)(I - B) -1 x<br />

= M3M2M1x<br />

= Mx (2.6)<br />

where D = (I - B) -1 C, <strong>and</strong><br />

M1 = (I - B) -1 =<br />

⎡<br />

⎢<br />

⎣<br />

−<br />

−1<br />

( I ANN<br />

) 0<br />

0 ( I − A )<br />

VV<br />

−1<br />

⎤<br />

⎥<br />

⎦<br />

(2.7)<br />

is a matrix of domestic economywide multiplier effects. These are the st<strong>and</strong>ard multipliers<br />

from domestic production-factor-consumption linkages <strong>and</strong> could be further decomposed with<br />

methods proposed by Stone (1981) or Pyatt <strong>and</strong> Round (1979). The NN block in the upper left corner<br />

corresponds to the st<strong>and</strong>ard SAM multiplier matrix for the single Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region. The<br />

second factor matrix details the so called direct or open loop linkages between regions, i.e.,<br />

where, e.g.<br />

M2 = (I + D) =<br />

⎡ I<br />

⎢<br />

⎣D<br />

VN<br />

−1<br />

NV VV NV<br />

D<br />

NV<br />

I<br />

⎤<br />

⎥<br />

(2.8)<br />

⎦<br />

D = ( I - A ) A defines cumulative unrequited flows from ROV to the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, taking account of the combined effects of cumulative intra-regional effects <strong>and</strong> the<br />

direct transfers from ROV to the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. Finally, closed loop effects are detailed in the<br />

third factor matrix<br />

M 3 = (I - D 2 ) -1 =<br />

⎡E<br />

⎢<br />

⎣E<br />

NN<br />

VN<br />

E<br />

E<br />

NV<br />

VV<br />

⎤<br />

⎥<br />

⎦<br />

Page 171


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

=<br />

⎡I − D<br />

NV<br />

DVN DNV<br />

⎢<br />

⎣ D I − D D<br />

VN VN NV<br />

⎤<br />

⎥<br />

⎦<br />

−1<br />

(2.9)<br />

This last factor matrix represents the income effects originating in one (column) region,<br />

passing through trade linkages, <strong>and</strong> returning to the recipient (row) region. The Eij multipliers<br />

aggregate all the indirect income gains accruing between i <strong>and</strong> j from the existing pattern of domestic<br />

economic linkages.<br />

The Mi matrices enter the decomposition multiplicatively <strong>and</strong> the contribution of each to<br />

economy wide income generation is difficult to interpret directly. It is more transparent to use the<br />

additive component matrices<br />

N1 = M1 (2.10)<br />

N2 = (M2 - I)M1 (2.11)<br />

N3 = (M3 - I)M2M1 (2.12)<br />

which together satisfy M = N1 + N2 + N3.<br />

7.4.2 Decomposition of income-expenditure linkages<br />

To better ascertain the determinants of incomes in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, we applied the<br />

multiplier decomposition technique described above to the two-region SAM. The results of this<br />

analysis strongly support the conclusions set forth at the outset of this chapter, particularly the<br />

importance to rural households of emerging from subsistence production patterns with diversification<br />

toward more marketable <strong>and</strong> profitable crops <strong>and</strong> tertiary activities. In this section, we provide a brief<br />

summary of this analysis, indication how the main conclusions are elucidated by detailed linkage<br />

analysis, <strong>and</strong> giving indications about how the data resources developed for this project can be more<br />

intensively utilized in the future.<br />

Given the size of the two-region table (199x199), it is impossible to cover all the elements of<br />

the decomposition analysis within the limits of this chapter. Thus, we shall instead focus this research<br />

tool on the essential issues of economic diversification <strong>and</strong> market access. In this regard, Table 7-8<br />

presents the total multiplier effects (column 4) on each production activity, as these would result from<br />

a 1000 Dong increase in final dem<strong>and</strong> for the corresponding commodity. Further, this total effect is<br />

decomposed into the three parts alluded to above: intra-regional effect (column 1), direct interregional<br />

(column 2), <strong>and</strong> indirect inter-regional (column 3).<br />

Two of the main conclusions of our analysis emerge instantly from these results. First, the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s’s net economic linkages to the rest of the national <strong>and</strong> global economy are<br />

Page 172


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

extremely weak, in every commodity representing less than 10% of total income effects. Secondly, it<br />

is obvious that the main subsistence crop, rice, has the lowest economic potential of any agricultural<br />

product, particularly when compared to more diversified crops <strong>and</strong> animal husb<strong>and</strong>ry of any kind.<br />

Clearly, any reduction in rice output occasioned by crop substitution would have to be offset<br />

by higher income to finance food purchases, but the average multiplier effects for more diverse<br />

agricultural products are 3 to 3.5 times higher than those of rice. If agricultural terms of trade could<br />

remain stable, returns to rural producers would rise dramatically with diversification. The most<br />

attractive activities at the margin appear to be Poultry, Forestry, <strong>and</strong> Aquaculture, all of which are<br />

appropriate to this regional economy. Only Aquaculture might face market access barriers because of<br />

inadequate transport infrastructure, but there appears to be a significant premium to diversification in<br />

the other (<strong>and</strong> indeed most non-subsistence) activities.<br />

Tables 7-9 to 7-11 focus more closely on microeconomic impacts, detailing income effects on<br />

individual household types. For a 1000 Dong dem<strong>and</strong> increase in each commodity in the right-h<strong>and</strong><br />

column, the corresponding column indicates how much long term household income would rise. The<br />

three tables decompose this household income effect into the same three components discussed<br />

earlier.<br />

Again we immediately see the two main conclusions: very low extra-regional expenditureincome<br />

linkages <strong>and</strong> low relative returns to subsistence crops. Even assuming rice generated a<br />

marketable surplus, it is evidentially the least desirable product available in terms of income generated<br />

for any household group. Most other agricultural products yield 7-9 times as much final income,<br />

largely because of their more extensive linkages to the rest of the regional economy. This reveals the<br />

double trap of subsistence agriculture. Because farm enterprises focus on production for own use, they<br />

generate little cash income or the savings necessary to finance real growth <strong>and</strong> higher productivity.<br />

Secondly, because this high subsistence production is a region-wide phenomenon, the market for<br />

subsistence products like rice is quite weak <strong>and</strong> offers little incentive to market (or invest in)<br />

surpluses. Only diversification can break out of this double bind.<br />

Clearly (from the last two tables) the market potential of Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s products, in the<br />

rest of the country <strong>and</strong> internationally, is far from being realized. In many more highly articulated<br />

regional economies, indirect income-expenditure effects can often be larger than direct effects. The<br />

very weak extra-regional linkages in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s are the result of a combination of<br />

inappropriate products (i.e. lack of informed diversification) <strong>and</strong> (physical <strong>and</strong> informational)<br />

constraints on market access. A concerted effort by regional, national, <strong>and</strong> international development<br />

authorities will be needed to overcome this barrier. Having said this, the virtue of a small market share<br />

starting point is that terms of trade will likely remain stable even with dramatic expansion of<br />

marketing possibilities. This means the difficult experience of the coffee sector is unlikely to<br />

undermine proactive agricultural development <strong>and</strong> diversification in this area.<br />

Page 173


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

Table 7.8: Sectoral Multiplier Linkages to NMR<br />

(all figures in Dong per 1000 Dong change in commodity dem<strong>and</strong>)<br />

N1 N2 N3 Total<br />

1 Rice 2159 104 5 2268<br />

2 Raw Rubber 5490 125 22 5637<br />

3 Coffee Bean 5744 78 23 5845<br />

4 Sugar Cane 6900 108 28 7036<br />

5 Other Crops 6903 106 28 7037<br />

6 Pigs 6360 117 34 6511<br />

7 Poultry 7040 116 29 7184<br />

8 Other Livestock 6863 113 30 7007<br />

9 Irrigation Services 6006 110 37 6153<br />

10 Other Ag. Services 5757 122 34 5913<br />

11 Forestry 7223 110 31 7364<br />

12 Fishery 7097 107 30 7234<br />

13 Energy 6189 31 27 6247<br />

14 Mining 5825 93 32 5949<br />

15 Processed Meat 7713 133 28 7874<br />

16 Dairy 5553 97 45 5694<br />

17 Fruits <strong>and</strong> Vegetables 6561 126 35 6721<br />

18 Sugar 7524 99 26 7649<br />

19 Coffee Beverages 7028 311 34 7374<br />

20 Other Bev <strong>and</strong> Tobacco 5735 94 29 5858<br />

21 Seafood 8222 271 30 8523<br />

22 Animal Feed 6692 189 29 6910<br />

23 Other Proc. Food 6132 112 32 6275<br />

24 Building Materials 5726 184 63 5973<br />

25 Industrial Chemicals 4459 73 31 4563<br />

26 Ag. Chemicals 4805 74 26 4905<br />

27 Techincal Mfg 1000 60 0 1060<br />

28 Vehicles 1000 58 0 1058<br />

29 Machinery 4910 54 22 4987<br />

30 Metal Products 5055 63 24 5142<br />

31 Textile <strong>and</strong> Apparel 5558 277 34 5869<br />

32 Other Industry 4894 110 46 5050<br />

33 Utilities 4403 42 12 4457<br />

34 Construction 5226 203 79 5508<br />

35 Commercial Trade 5634 127 23 5784<br />

36 Transport Services 4541 65 16 4622<br />

37 Other Private Serv 6925 106 33 7064<br />

38 Public Services 7057 121 37 7214<br />

Page 174


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

7.5 Summary<br />

After examining these issues with a variety of analytical techniques (discussed below), we<br />

offer three general conclusions of relevance to the larger research activity. First, the existing patterns<br />

of farming are not realizing the region’s potential for more diversified agricultural activity. There<br />

appears to be significant scope for crop substitution in the direction of products that are more<br />

marketable <strong>and</strong> profitable at the regional, national, <strong>and</strong> international level. Moreover, given the<br />

relatively small market share of Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s products in the Rest of Vietnam (ROV) <strong>and</strong> in total<br />

Vietnamese exports, such shifts could rapidly increase rural incomes <strong>and</strong> savings, accelerating both<br />

economic growth <strong>and</strong> the diversification process.<br />

Second, the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s trade with both ROV <strong>and</strong> the Rest of the World (ROW) is well<br />

below national averages, <strong>and</strong> far below the potential indicated by its relative production costs.<br />

Because of these small market shares, the agricultural terms of trade for the region, internally <strong>and</strong><br />

nationally, would likely remain stable even if agricultural trade increased by multiples of its present<br />

levels. For this reason, greater market orientation in regional agriculture should be strongly promoted.<br />

Third, despite low production costs, the margins for agricultural marketing in the region are<br />

relatively high because of insufficiency in transport, communications, <strong>and</strong> other commercial<br />

infrastructure. For this reason, the government should make investments in improved market access<br />

an essential component of <strong>and</strong> program for agricultural diversification <strong>and</strong> trade promotion. Without<br />

these, it may be unreasonable to expect many farmers to emerge from subsistence production patterns.<br />

Page 175


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

Table 7.9: Multiplier Linkages in the NMR (N1) : Household <strong>Income</strong> from Commodities<br />

(all figures in Dong per 1000 Dong change in commodity dem<strong>and</strong>)<br />

HH01RF HH02RS HH03RW HH05UF HH06US HH07UW Total<br />

1 Rice 64 40 18 28 11 13 174<br />

2 Raw Rubber 233 243 58 169 43 32 778<br />

3 Coffee Bean 305 247 63 197 43 41 896<br />

4 Sugar Cane 527 308 81 323 50 57 1346<br />

5 Other Crops 537 281 85 299 53 55 1310<br />

6 Pigs 361 158 74 174 42 49 857<br />

7 Poultry 605 231 85 347 41 60 1369<br />

8 Other Livestock 486 199 77 272 43 50 1126<br />

9 Irrigation Services 327 124 60 188 28 36 764<br />

10 Other Ag. Services 332 127 60 189 29 37 775<br />

11 Forestry 582 233 136 221 87 82 1342<br />

12 Fishery 544 180 123 205 75 74 1202<br />

13 Energy 443 159 113 203 52 63 1032<br />

14 Mining 302 112 74 146 35 41 709<br />

15 Processed Meat 477 177 95 227 55 59 1089<br />

16 Dairy 225 86 47 106 30 28 523<br />

17 Fruits <strong>and</strong> Vegetables 389 166 84 180 50 49 919<br />

18 Sugar 407 221 77 236 46 48 1036<br />

19 Coffee Beverages 531 178 131 199 82 76 1198<br />

20 Other Bev <strong>and</strong> Tobacco 315 133 80 149 48 43 768<br />

21 Seafood 521 174 124 196 75 73 1163<br />

22 Animal Feed 450 166 108 195 58 63 1041<br />

23 Other Proc. Food 358 140 84 158 54 48 843<br />

24 Building Materials 267 110 72 126 40 38 652<br />

25 Industrial Chemicals 210 79 55 93 29 30 495<br />

26 Ag. Chemicals 215 79 56 97 29 30 505<br />

27 Techincal Mfg 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

28 Vehicles 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

29 Machinery 262 99 76 119 37 39 632<br />

30 Metal Products 251 95 68 116 35 36 601<br />

31 Textile <strong>and</strong> Apparel 273 96 73 96 49 40 627<br />

32 Other Industry 231 90 60 107 32 32 553<br />

33 Utilities 151 87 55 106 26 22 446<br />

34 Construction 211 81 62 95 28 34 511<br />

35 Commercial Trade 446 135 115 120 80 66 963<br />

36 Transport Services 172 93 59 116 27 24 491<br />

37 Other Private Serv 550 186 95 290 47 55 1222<br />

38 Public Services 548 182 103 265 56 60 1214<br />

Page 176


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

Table 7.10: Open Loop Multiplier Linkages from ROV to NMR (N2)<br />

(all figures in Dong per 1000 Dong change in commodity dem<strong>and</strong>)<br />

HH01RF HH02RS HH03RW HH05UF HH06US HH07UW Total<br />

1 Rice 5 2 1 2 1 1 12<br />

2 Raw Rubber 22 21 5 15 4 3 70<br />

3 Coffee Bean 28 22 6 18 4 4 81<br />

4 Sugar Cane 5 2 1 2 1 1 12<br />

5 Other Crops 7 3 1 3 1 1 17<br />

6 Pigs 7 3 2 3 1 1 17<br />

7 Poultry 8 3 2 4 1 1 18<br />

8 Other Livestock 6 2 1 3 1 1 14<br />

9 Irrigation Services 5 2 1 2 1 1 11<br />

10 Other Ag. Services 6 2 1 3 1 1 13<br />

11 Forestry 6 2 1 3 1 1 13<br />

12 Fishery 7 2 2 3 1 1 15<br />

13 Energy 2 1 1 1 0 0 6<br />

14 Mining 5 2 1 2 1 1 11<br />

15 Processed Meat 11 4 2 5 1 1 26<br />

16 Dairy 3 1 1 1 0 0 7<br />

17 Fruits <strong>and</strong> Vegetables 11 4 2 5 1 1 25<br />

18 Sugar 6 3 1 3 1 1 14<br />

19 Coffee Beverages 27 13 6 13 4 4 66<br />

20 Other Bev <strong>and</strong> Tobacco 5 2 1 2 1 1 12<br />

21 Seafood 81 27 19 31 12 11 181<br />

22 Animal Feed 6 2 1 3 1 1 14<br />

23 Other Proc. Food 5 2 1 2 1 1 12<br />

24 Building Materials 19 8 5 9 3 3 47<br />

25 Industrial Chemicals 1 0 0 1 0 0 3<br />

26 Ag. Chemicals 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

27 Techincal Mfg 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

28 Vehicles 1 0 0 1 0 0 3<br />

29 Machinery 0 0 0 0 0 0 1<br />

30 Metal Products 1 0 0 0 0 0 2<br />

31 Textile <strong>and</strong> Apparel 13 5 3 5 2 2 31<br />

32 Other Industry 4 2 1 2 1 1 9<br />

33 Utilities 2 1 0 1 0 0 4<br />

34 Construction 8 3 2 4 1 1 19<br />

35 Commercial Trade 6 2 1 3 1 1 14<br />

36 Transport Services 5 2 2 3 1 1 14<br />

37 Other Private Serv 6 2 1 3 1 1 13<br />

38 Public Services 7 3 2 3 1 1 17<br />

Page 177


Chapter 7. A Social Accounting Analysis of Linkages<br />

Table 7.11: Closed Loop Multiplier Linkages to NMR (N3)<br />

(all figures in Dong per 1000 Dong change in commodity dem<strong>and</strong>)<br />

HH01RF HH02RS HH03RW HH05UF HH06US HH07UW Total<br />

1 Rice 0 0 0 0 0 0 1<br />

2 Raw Rubber 1 0 0 0 0 0 2<br />

3 Coffee Bean 1 0 0 0 0 0 2<br />

4 Sugar Cane 1 0 0 1 0 0 3<br />

5 Other Crops 1 0 0 1 0 0 3<br />

6 Pigs 2 1 0 1 0 0 4<br />

7 Poultry 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

8 Other Livestock 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

9 Irrigation Services 2 1 0 1 0 0 4<br />

10 Other Ag. Services 1 1 0 1 0 0 4<br />

11 Forestry 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

12 Fishery 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

13 Energy 1 0 0 1 0 0 3<br />

14 Mining 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

15 Processed Meat 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

16 Dairy 2 1 0 1 0 0 4<br />

17 Fruits <strong>and</strong> Vegetables 2 1 0 1 0 0 4<br />

18 Sugar 1 0 0 1 0 0 3<br />

19 Coffee Beverages 2 1 0 1 0 0 4<br />

20 Other Bev <strong>and</strong> Tobacco 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

21 Seafood 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

22 Animal Feed 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

23 Other Proc. Food 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

24 Building Materials 3 1 1 1 0 0 7<br />

25 Industrial Chemicals 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

26 Ag. Chemicals 1 0 0 1 0 0 3<br />

27 Techincal Mfg 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

28 Vehicles 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

29 Machinery 1 0 0 0 0 0 2<br />

30 Metal Products 1 0 0 1 0 0 3<br />

31 Textile <strong>and</strong> Apparel 2 1 0 1 0 0 4<br />

32 Other Industry 2 1 0 1 0 0 5<br />

33 Utilities 1 0 0 0 0 0 1<br />

34 Construction 3 1 1 2 0 0 8<br />

35 Commercial Trade 1 0 0 0 0 0 2<br />

36 Transport Services 1 0 0 0 0 0 2<br />

37 Other Private Serv 1 1 0 1 0 0 3<br />

38 Public Services 2 1 0 1 0 0 4<br />

Page 178


CHAPTER EIGHT<br />

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS<br />

8.1 Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

8.1.1 Introduction<br />

This report examines the process of income diversification in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s of<br />

Vietnam. We use three related but distinct definitions of income diversification: the diversity of<br />

income sources, the shift from subsistence to commercial production, <strong>and</strong> the shift from producing<br />

low-value staple crops to producing high-value crops, livestock, <strong>and</strong> fishery products, as well as the<br />

shift into non-farm activities. In this report, patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in all three are examined, but the<br />

focus is on diversification into high-value crops <strong>and</strong> non-crop activities.<br />

The objectives of the project are to describe the patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification, to<br />

assess its contribution to income growth <strong>and</strong> poverty reduction, to identify constraints to further<br />

diversification, <strong>and</strong> to recommend ways the government can facilitate diversification <strong>and</strong> maximize its<br />

benefits for poor households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

The project has three components, each involving a different method to examine the issue of<br />

diversification. The first component is a comparison of three national household surveys: the two<br />

Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Surveys carried out in 1992-93 <strong>and</strong> 1997-98 <strong>and</strong> the Vietnam Household<br />

Living Survey implemented in 2002. These data are used to study changes in the sources of income,<br />

the contribution of income diversification to income growth <strong>and</strong> poverty reduction, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

determinants of food dem<strong>and</strong>. The second component is a Qualitative Social Assessment of <strong>Income</strong><br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> (QSAID), which involved interviews with some 300 rural households, 90 traders, <strong>and</strong><br />

roughly 100 local government officials. The interviews focused on experiences with income<br />

diversification <strong>and</strong> perceived constraints on diversification. The third component involves the<br />

construction of a social accounting matrix (SAM) of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s economy to analyze the<br />

inter-sectoral linkages.<br />

8.1.2 Background on diversification <strong>and</strong> the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Why do rural households adopt multiple income sources rather than specializing Several<br />

reasons can be identified: to reduce the risk associated with fluctuations in any one income source, to<br />

take advantage of complementarities between activities, to adapt to poorly-functioning markets, to<br />

respond to different skills of members of the household, or to satisfy diverse consumption needs.<br />

Previous research indicates that growing many crops (particularly food crops) is associated with poor<br />

households living in remote areas with low or uncertain rainfall.<br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong>, diversification into high-value commercial crops <strong>and</strong> non-farm activities is<br />

sometimes associated with higher-income households with good market access. Many poor<br />

Page 179


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

households are not able to participate in these activities because of barriers to entry. They may lack<br />

necessary skills, social capital 1 , information about the market, or liquidity to cover high investment<br />

<strong>and</strong> bear risks associated with these activities. When poor households are able to participate, it is<br />

often because of institutional arrangements (such as contract farming) in which the buyer provides<br />

farmers with inputs, credit, <strong>and</strong> technical assistance.<br />

Some argue that diversification into commercial crops <strong>and</strong> non-farm activities threatens food<br />

security <strong>and</strong> nutrition, though studies generally show that, by raising income, diversification improves<br />

living conditions <strong>and</strong> food security. Others argue that diversification contributes to economic <strong>and</strong><br />

social inequalities. There is some evidence to support this argument, but this does not imply higher<br />

poverty; in fact, income growth often offsets the effect of inequality, leading to lower poverty rates.<br />

Turning our attention to the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, the region can be characterized as follows:<br />

• The topography is hilly to mountainous, with altitudes typically between 500 <strong>and</strong> 1000<br />

meters but with some mountainous areas with peaks above 3000 meters.<br />

• The infrastructure is poor, leading to communities being relatively isolated from the rest<br />

of the economy.<br />

• The population density is low (111 people/km 2 ) compared to the country as a whole (231<br />

people/km 2 ).<br />

• Roughly half the population is a member of an ethnic minority, compared to just 12<br />

percent nationally.<br />

• The region is less urbanized <strong>and</strong> more dependent on the agricultural sector than other<br />

regions of Vietnam.<br />

• And the incidence of poverty is probably highest in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, though some<br />

studies rank the North Central Coast <strong>and</strong> the Central Highl<strong>and</strong>s as equally poor.<br />

Nonetheless, there is considerable diversify across the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. The topography is<br />

highest <strong>and</strong> most rugged in Lai Chau, Lai Cau, <strong>and</strong> Son La, while provinces adjacent to the Red River<br />

Delta have significant lowl<strong>and</strong> areas. The infrastructure is better <strong>and</strong> the population density much<br />

higher in the provinces near the Delta such as Thai Nguyen, Bac Giang, <strong>and</strong> Phu Tho. Although<br />

ethnic minorities dominate in most of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, Kinh are the largest ethnic group in large<br />

areas of Thai Nguyen, Bac Giang, Phu Tho, <strong>and</strong> Quang Ninh. Furthermore, there is tremendous<br />

diversity in ethnic composition from one district to another. The level of urbanization varies from 7<br />

percent in Bac Giang to 44 percent in Quang Ninh. Similarly, the incidence of poverty varies widely,<br />

being highest in the border provinces such as Lai Chau, Ha Giang, <strong>and</strong> Son La <strong>and</strong> lowest in Quang<br />

Ninh <strong>and</strong> provinces adjacent to the Delta.<br />

Some general trends in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s can be identified by comparing agricultural<br />

statistics for 1995 <strong>and</strong> 2000. The area allocated to rice has been almost unchanged over this period,<br />

1<br />

The “social capital” of an entrepreneur refers to his/her network of business associates with whom<br />

there is some degree of mutual trust. In markets where it is difficult to enforce contracts in the courts, having a<br />

reputation for trustworthiness <strong>and</strong> knowing who can be trusted are important assets for agricultural traders <strong>and</strong><br />

other entrepreneurs.<br />

Page 180


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

but rice production has grown significantly due to rising yields <strong>and</strong>, to a lesser extent, cropping<br />

intensification. At the same time, there is evidence of crop diversification in that the share of crop<br />

l<strong>and</strong> allocated to non-rice crops <strong>and</strong> non-food crops has increased by 5-6 percentage points. Although<br />

the agricultural sector is growing rapidly (6 percent per year), the agricultural share of GDP has fallen<br />

from 47 percent to 42 percent over this period, indicating that non-agricultural diversification is<br />

occurring at the regional level. Finally, the growth in agricultural GDP per hectare suggests a trend of<br />

diversification into higher-value crops <strong>and</strong> other agricultural activities.<br />

8.1.3 Patterns <strong>and</strong> trends in diversification<br />

The comparison of the three surveys indicates substantial growth in income <strong>and</strong> expenditure<br />

over 1993-98 <strong>and</strong> more modest but respectable growth over 1998-2002. The gains for rural<br />

households have been widespread across regions <strong>and</strong> types of households. In the rural Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s, per capita expenditure grew 32 percent between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998, or almost 6 percent per<br />

year, a figure roughly consistent with national accounts. Comparing the 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002<br />

VHLSS, per capita expenditure grew 11 percent. This is less than would be suggested by national<br />

accounts data, raising questions about the comparability of the two surveys 2 .<br />

Although there is today a wider gap between poor <strong>and</strong> rich households than in 1993,<br />

paradoxically those who were poor in 1993 gained as much on average as those who had relatively<br />

high incomes in 1993. Thus, there is little evidence that the rural poor have, in general, been “left<br />

behind” (either in relative or in absolute terms) with the rise in st<strong>and</strong>ards of living over the 1990s.<br />

Crop production continues to be the most important source of income for rural households,<br />

accounting for 38 percent of the net income in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. Poor rural households depend<br />

even more on crop income than other rural households. Staple food crops, particularly rice, continue<br />

to play a dominant role in crop production. Rice alone accounts for 46 percent of the net value of<br />

crop production (the percentage is even higher in other regions of Vietnam).<br />

Among rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, there is evidence of increased diversity in<br />

broad income categories, <strong>and</strong> well as increased diversity in crop production. It is also worth noting<br />

that diversity in crop production is generally higher among poor households than rich, <strong>and</strong> greater<br />

among rural households than urban ones. Farmers in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s have the most diverse<br />

cropping systems, growing over eight crops on average. This is consistent with the international<br />

patterns discussed above, in which poor farmers with limited market access grow numerous crops to<br />

reduce risk <strong>and</strong> satisfy diverse food consumption dem<strong>and</strong>s with home production.<br />

There is also clear evidence of increasing commercial orientation among farmers in the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. The share of crop production that is marketed rose from 22 percent to 33 percent<br />

in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> from 40 to 61 percent in rural areas as a whole. Although poor<br />

2<br />

The VHLSS data used in this analysis are preliminary data, so that further cleaning of the data may<br />

resolve this issue.<br />

Page 181


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

households are less commercially oriented, households in all income categories shifted toward<br />

commercial production over this period.<br />

If we define diversification in terms of the shift toward high-value crops, livestock, fisheries,<br />

<strong>and</strong> non-farm income sources, several conclusions emerge. Between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998, all sectors grew<br />

at similar rates so the percentage composition did not change markedly 3 . Between 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002, the<br />

share of income from agriculture shrank, while that of forestry <strong>and</strong> wages increased, though this may<br />

have been the result of differences in the way the two surveys were designed. There is evidence of<br />

crop diversification, with farmers reducing the area planted with rice <strong>and</strong> increasing the area planted<br />

to either sugarcane <strong>and</strong> fruit (according to the 1998 VLSS) or maize <strong>and</strong> tea (according to the 2002<br />

VHLSS).<br />

Non-agricultural income among rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s accounted for 34<br />

percent of total income 2002, <strong>and</strong> it represented 37 percent of the growth in income between 1998 <strong>and</strong><br />

2002. Thus, non-farm income is important in the livelihoods of rural households, but it’s importance<br />

grew only slowly.<br />

Over 1993-1998, the growth in crop income growth accounted for 45 percent of the growth in<br />

overall income for the average rural household in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, but the percentage is higher<br />

among the poorest income group (69 percent) <strong>and</strong> among ethnic minority households (74 percent).<br />

Decomposing crop income growth, 40 percent is attributable to higher yields, 28 percent to higher real<br />

prices, 15 percent to expansion in sown area, <strong>and</strong> 6 percent to diversification into higher-value crops 4 .<br />

Nationally, crop diversification accounts for 12 percent of the growth in crop income.<br />

The sources of crop income growth vary across income groups. Poor households increased<br />

their crop income largely by achieving higher yields, particularly for rice, while richer households<br />

increased their incomes by exp<strong>and</strong>ing the area cultivated. The contribution of diversification shows<br />

an uneven pattern across income categories.<br />

8.1.4 Analysis of food dem<strong>and</strong> patterns<br />

The patterns of diversification are in part driven by rising incomes <strong>and</strong> its effect in changing<br />

the composition of dem<strong>and</strong>. As incomes rise, the share of the budget spent on food declines <strong>and</strong><br />

within the food budget, consumers shift from staple foods (grains <strong>and</strong> tubers than are inexpensive<br />

sources of calories) to animal products, processed foods, <strong>and</strong>, to a lesser extent, fruits <strong>and</strong> vegetables.<br />

In order to assess the impact of rising income on the domestic dem<strong>and</strong> for agricultural commodities,<br />

we carried out an analysis of the determinants of food dem<strong>and</strong> using the 1998 Vietnam Living<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey. The national dem<strong>and</strong> for 14 food categories was estimated econometrically as a<br />

3<br />

Although the share of income from non-farm enterprises did not change, the percentage of rural<br />

households operating an enterprise fell sharply, suggesting consolidation in which there are fewer enterprises<br />

but they are larger on average.<br />

4<br />

Area expansion includes the effect of increasing cropping intensity. The sum is not equal to 100<br />

percent because there is some interaction among the four components.<br />

Page 182


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

function of income, prices, <strong>and</strong> household characteristics. We used Zellner’s seemingly unrelated<br />

regression model <strong>and</strong> imposed symmetry on the cross-price terms, to conform with dem<strong>and</strong> theory.<br />

The analysis confirms that the dem<strong>and</strong> for meat, sugar, beverages, <strong>and</strong> “other food” (mainly<br />

processed foods <strong>and</strong> prepared meals) are more income-elastic than other foods. For an average<br />

household, the income elasticity of meat is 1.2, while those of sugar, beverages, <strong>and</strong> “other food”<br />

were 1.0 or greater. This suggests that, in the absence of changes in relative prices <strong>and</strong> demographic<br />

patterns, the dem<strong>and</strong> for these items will rise as quickly as or more quickly than per capita income<br />

over time. The income elasticities for fruits, vegetables, fish, <strong>and</strong> cooking oil were in the range of<br />

0.50 <strong>and</strong> 0.90. This implies that, other things being equal, the dem<strong>and</strong> for these commodities will rise<br />

as incomes rise, but at a slower pace. The income elasticity of rice is 0.31, suggesting that rice<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> will rise only slowly over time. The income elasticities of maize <strong>and</strong> cassava are negative<br />

(though only cassava is significantly less than zero), indicating stagnant or falling dem<strong>and</strong> for these<br />

commodities for human consumption as incomes rise. This does not include the dem<strong>and</strong> for maize for<br />

animal feed, which is rising sharply as meat dem<strong>and</strong> rises <strong>and</strong> as the livestock sector turns toward<br />

industrial production that relies on feed rather than grazing.<br />

8.1.5 <strong>Income</strong> diversification from the farmers’ perspective<br />

The project carried out a Qualitative Social Assessment of <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> (QSAID),<br />

which entailed semi-structured interviews with rural households, local authorities, <strong>and</strong> traders. The<br />

household interviews used a semi-structured 9-page questionnaire administered to a sample of 307<br />

households in 32 villages, located in 16 communes <strong>and</strong> eight Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> provinces. An index<br />

of accessibility was constructed based on the commune-level “hardship factors” used by the<br />

Vietnamese government to adjust salaries of public-sector employees posted in rural areas. In<br />

addition, an index of st<strong>and</strong>ard of living was calculated based on a) household characteristics including<br />

the size <strong>and</strong> composition of the household, education of the head, housing characteristics, <strong>and</strong><br />

ownership of several consumer durables, <strong>and</strong> b) the relationship between those characteristics <strong>and</strong> per<br />

capita expenditure in the 1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey (VLSS).<br />

The results of the QSAID confirm the finding from the VLSS data that st<strong>and</strong>ards of living in<br />

the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s have improved significantly. Fully 83 percent of the respondents said that<br />

their st<strong>and</strong>ard of living was higher today than in 1994 <strong>and</strong> just 1 percent (3 households) reported a<br />

deterioration. Most households (62 percent) reported that their own food production was enough to<br />

supply them for 12 months per year <strong>and</strong> about two-thirds (69 percent) said that they did not<br />

experience any hungry months over the course of the year. When asked about the reasons for their<br />

improved st<strong>and</strong>ard of living, 80 percent cited higher crop yields, 62 percent mentioned higher<br />

livestock income, <strong>and</strong> 47 percent said that they now grow new, more profitable crops. The<br />

importance of yield increases in income growth confirms the results of the VLSS, though the<br />

importance of livestock income <strong>and</strong> crop diversification seems greater in the QSAID than would be<br />

Page 183


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

expected based on the VLSS analysis. Part of the explanation may be that the QSAID uses a<br />

difference reference period (1994-2002) than the VLSS analysis (1993-98). The poorest respondents<br />

were more likely to cite yield improvements, while their higher income neighbors were more likely to<br />

mention crop diversification <strong>and</strong> diversification into non-farm activities. These results also mirror<br />

those obtained from the VLSS.<br />

Staple food crops remain important in rural livelihoods, however. Ninety-one percent of the<br />

respondents said that rice was among the top three sources of income. Pigs, maize, <strong>and</strong> poultry were<br />

each listed among the top three sources by over 70 percent of the households. Non-farm income was<br />

somewhat more common among higher-income households than poorer households.<br />

An impressive 83 percent of the respondents had adopted at least one new crop or source of<br />

income since 1994, the most common ones being litchi, other fruit, tea, <strong>and</strong> “other industrial crops”.<br />

Fewer households reported giving up a crop or income source, the most common ones being cassava,<br />

beans, <strong>and</strong> opium. Farmers report that the share of income from rice, maize, pigs, buffalo, tea, <strong>and</strong><br />

litchi has increased, while that of cassava, poultry, <strong>and</strong> firewood has decreased. Fifty-six percent had<br />

successfully adopted at least one new crop (where success is defined by continued cultivation),<br />

although successful adoption is considerably less common among poor <strong>and</strong> remote households. Tea,<br />

litchi, anise, <strong>and</strong> new varieties of rice were the most frequently mentioned. Friends <strong>and</strong> extension<br />

agents are most commonly credited with encouraging the adoption of the new crop <strong>and</strong> farmers<br />

received inputs on sale or on credit in over half the cases. About one-quarter reported unsuccessful<br />

experiences with new crops, plum <strong>and</strong> apricot being mentioned most frequently. One of the most<br />

common problems mentioned was that production campaigns promote crops without adequate<br />

consideration of market potential, leading to flooded markets <strong>and</strong> low prices.<br />

Regarding the role of traders, there appears to be little or no “vertical coordination 5 ” between<br />

farmers <strong>and</strong> buyers. Farmers sell on spot markets <strong>and</strong> receive virtually no guidance or any other<br />

assistance from buyers. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, farmers generally have a choice of buyers <strong>and</strong> seem to<br />

trust that the prices they receive are fair. There is little evidence that farmers feel they are being<br />

“exploited,” even in the most remote villages.<br />

Extension agents <strong>and</strong> local government officials are quite involved in the process of<br />

diversification. Over half the respondents had received guidance or assistance on new crops from an<br />

extension agent, <strong>and</strong> three-quarter felt the assistance was useful. The respondents had clear views on<br />

what types of activities could help the poor. Three-quarters (72 percent) agreed that raising fish or<br />

livestock would help the poor; about half (52 percent) said that growing different crops would help;<br />

but just 18 percent said that small businesses or wage income would assist the poor raise their<br />

5<br />

“Vertical coordination” refers to various types of communication between buyers <strong>and</strong> sellers to<br />

ensure that supply <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> match each other in terms of product, quality, timing, <strong>and</strong> location. In<br />

agriculture, vertical coordination often takes the form of buyers providing seeds, chemicals, <strong>and</strong> technical<br />

assistance to farmers in exchange for the farmer agreeing to sell to the buyer.<br />

Page 184


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

incomes. Regarding the constraints, the most common response was “lack of capital”, but lack of<br />

labor, animal disease, lack of seed/seedlings, <strong>and</strong> lack of pasture were also cited. When asked about<br />

the most useful forms of government intervention, 24 percent said better access to credit, 20 percent<br />

cited better support 6 for existing crops, <strong>and</strong> 12 percent mentioned promotion of new crops. Among<br />

the most remote villages, greater weight was put on infrastructure improvements (roads, water, <strong>and</strong><br />

electricity) <strong>and</strong> less weight on credit.<br />

8.1.6 <strong>Income</strong> diversification from local governments’ perspective<br />

The Qualitative Social Assessment of <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> (QSAID) involved interviews<br />

with local authorities in eight provinces, 16 districts, <strong>and</strong> 16 communes in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. The<br />

interviews covered various topics including the types of diversification being undertaken, the policies<br />

being implemented to support diversification, <strong>and</strong> the perceived constraints at the farm level.<br />

The types of diversification vary by province. Most provinces cited diversification into fruit<br />

<strong>and</strong> tea, but a wide range of new crops were mentioned by local officials including anise, cinnamon,<br />

cardamom, sugarcane, coffee, bamboo, flax, tobacco, <strong>and</strong> soybeans. Farmers are also adopting new<br />

varieties of rice <strong>and</strong> hybrid maize in much of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. Local officials report that there is<br />

little diversification into livestock <strong>and</strong> non-farm enterprises, though it is possible that they are less<br />

aware of these sectors because they are less involved in supporting them.<br />

Some diversification is occurring in most districts of the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, but the pace of<br />

diversification is greater in areas with good market access. Furthermore, the type of diversification<br />

depends on the degree of market access. In provinces close to Hanoi <strong>and</strong> the delta, farmers are<br />

diversifying into litchi, longan, <strong>and</strong> other fruit crops. Farther out, farmers are diversifying into tea,<br />

sugarcane, <strong>and</strong> tobacco. And in the most remote provinces, any diversification that occurs tends to be<br />

into maize or cattle production.<br />

Local authorities are quite active in identifying <strong>and</strong> promoting promising new crops. They<br />

use various policy tools to encourage the adoption of new varieties including input subsidies,<br />

transportation subsidies, extension assistance, low-interest loans, l<strong>and</strong> allocation policy, l<strong>and</strong> use<br />

restrictions, <strong>and</strong> (less often) marketing assistance. Traders seem not to be very involved in promoting<br />

new crops, according to interviews with local officials, households, <strong>and</strong> traders.<br />

Constraints to diversification include unfavorable production conditions, the low level of<br />

education <strong>and</strong> training of farmers, population pressure on l<strong>and</strong> resources, lack of credit, <strong>and</strong> poor<br />

infrastructure. Inappropriate development projects, lack of markets, <strong>and</strong> weak extension services<br />

were also mentioned. Although the respondents did not explain what they meant by “inappropriate<br />

development projects,” interviews revealed numerous cases of crops being promoted that later turned<br />

6<br />

Although the respondents were not asked to define “support”, we assume it refers to assistance from<br />

researchers <strong>and</strong> extension agents to introduce new varieties <strong>and</strong> production methods that increase yields, manage<br />

pests <strong>and</strong> disease, <strong>and</strong> use inputs more effectively.<br />

Page 185


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

out not to have a market, of the distribution of seeds <strong>and</strong> planting materials with low germination<br />

rates, or seeds being provided with insufficient training on production methods.<br />

8.1.7 Social accounting analysis<br />

A social accounting matrix is table that summarizes the circular flow of money <strong>and</strong> goods<br />

through the economy. It includes the purchases <strong>and</strong> sales among industries (the input-output table) as<br />

well as the flows from industries to factors of production to households to industries, to <strong>and</strong> from the<br />

public sector, <strong>and</strong> international trade. In this project, three types of SAM models were developed: a<br />

set of aggregated SAMs for each province in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, a highly disaggregated SAM for<br />

the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> a two-region SAM model for examining the links between the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the rest of Vietnam.<br />

The analysis of the SAMs leads to three general conclusions. First, the existing patterns of<br />

farming are not realizing the region’s potential for more diversified agricultural activity. There<br />

appears to be significant scope for crop substitution in the direction of products that are more<br />

marketable <strong>and</strong> profitable at the regional, national, <strong>and</strong> international level. Moreover, given the<br />

relatively small market share of Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s products in the rest of Vietnam <strong>and</strong> in total<br />

Vietnamese exports, such shifts could rapidly increase rural incomes <strong>and</strong> savings, accelerating both<br />

economic growth <strong>and</strong> the diversification process.<br />

Second, trade between the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region <strong>and</strong> both the rest of Vietnam <strong>and</strong> the rest<br />

of the world is well below national averages, <strong>and</strong> far below the potential indicated by its relative<br />

production costs. Because of these small market shares, the agricultural terms of trade for the region,<br />

internally <strong>and</strong> nationally, would likely remain stable even if agricultural trade increased by multiples<br />

of its present levels. For this reason, greater market orientation in regional agriculture should be<br />

strongly promoted.<br />

Third, despite low production costs, the margins for agricultural marketing in the region are<br />

relatively high because of insufficiency in transport, communications, <strong>and</strong> other commercial<br />

infrastructure. For this reason, the government should make investments in improved market access<br />

an essential component of <strong>and</strong> program for agricultural diversification <strong>and</strong> trade promotion. Without<br />

these, it may be unreasonable to expect many farmers to emerge from subsistence production patterns.<br />

8.2 Conclusions <strong>and</strong> implications for policy<br />

This section draws some overall conclusions from this study <strong>and</strong> identifies some implications<br />

for rural development policy <strong>and</strong> public investment. In particular, we examine the implications for<br />

rural development strategy, agricultural research, extension, input subsidies, <strong>and</strong> public investment.<br />

Page 186


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

8.2.1 Implications for rural development strategy<br />

The social accounting matrix analysis, carried out as part of this study, suggests that the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s region has significant untapped potential for diversification into higher-value<br />

crops. This is based on the findings that diversification into higher-value activities would generate<br />

significantly higher incomes, <strong>and</strong> that region has an advantage as a low-cost producer for many of<br />

these commodities. Because the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s’ share of these products in the national <strong>and</strong><br />

international markets is too small to provoke a large decline in price. However, to realize these gains,<br />

it is necessary to reduce transport <strong>and</strong> marketing costs through improved road infrastructure in the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. These findings are consistent with econometric studies of investment in China <strong>and</strong><br />

India which suggest that public investment often has a higher return in less-favored regions 7 than in<br />

more-favored regions (Fan et al, 1999 <strong>and</strong> 2002).<br />

Growth in income <strong>and</strong> expenditure in the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s was been strong over the<br />

period 1993-1998 8 . Per capita expenditure growth in the region, one of the poorest in Vietnam, was<br />

almost 6 percent per year, equal to the nation-wide rural growth rate. Growth in estimated per capita<br />

income grew at an even greater pace, though income is less accurately measured in survey data. The<br />

strong growth in household income is a confirmation of the positive impact of the economic reforms<br />

carried out over the last 15 years. Giving responsibility for production decisions to individual<br />

households <strong>and</strong> greater assurance of l<strong>and</strong> tenure has increased the incentives for farmers to invest time<br />

<strong>and</strong> money in exp<strong>and</strong>ing production <strong>and</strong> making good use of resources.<br />

The main criticism of the market reforms is that they have widened the gap between rich <strong>and</strong><br />

poor <strong>and</strong> between urban <strong>and</strong> rural (see Henin, 2002). Inequality in rural areas increased slightly over<br />

this period. The growth in per capita income of the poorest quintile lagged behind the average,<br />

although the growth in per capita expenditure does not show this pattern. This is consistent with other<br />

analyses of the VLSS, which show significant growth in per capita expenditure, small increases in<br />

inequality, <strong>and</strong> overall poverty reduction (Joint Working Group, 2000). Furthermore, the growth in<br />

income <strong>and</strong> expenditure appears to have been slower among ethnic minorities than among other rural<br />

households. Thus, continued efforts to strengthen the productivity of poor households are needed if<br />

poor <strong>and</strong> ethnic minority households are to share fully in the benefits of economic growth.<br />

Crop production is by far the most important source of income for rural households.<br />

Furthermore, crop production has played a central role in income growth, contributing 45 percent of<br />

the growth in income over 1993-98. The implication is that rural development strategy must focus on<br />

ways to increase the labor <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> productivity of crop production, including yield increases,<br />

7<br />

In the study, western China is considered “less favored” because it has lower rainfall, poorer<br />

infrastructure, <strong>and</strong> less irrigation than other regions, <strong>and</strong> it is further from the large urban markets.<br />

8<br />

Growth in income <strong>and</strong> expenditure between 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2002 was slower according to the comparison<br />

of the 1998 VLSS <strong>and</strong> the 2002 VHLSS, but there is a question about the comparability of the two surveys.<br />

National accounts data show continued strong growth during this period.<br />

Page 187


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

diversification to high-value crops, <strong>and</strong> other means of increasing the economic returns to crop<br />

production 9 . This does not mean that the government <strong>and</strong> international organizations should ab<strong>and</strong>on<br />

efforts to develop livestock, aquaculture, non-farm enterprises, <strong>and</strong> other income sources, but these<br />

activities cannot be expected to reach the majority of rural households.<br />

The contribution of crop production in the income growth of the poorest farmers is greatest<br />

(69 percent) among the poorest farmers. Thus, policies <strong>and</strong> programs to raise the incomes of poor<br />

households must also focus on increasing the income from crop production. It may be argued that<br />

they are poor because they are specialized in agriculture, but this is misleading. It will take at least<br />

ten years for non-farm employment to become a major source of income in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

The absence of non-farm enterprises is a reflection of the composition of dem<strong>and</strong>. Rather than push<br />

them into non-farm activities, it is preferable to help farmers raise productivity in their existing<br />

activities, combined with measures to facilitate gradual diversification into other activities.<br />

<strong>Diversification</strong> from staple food crops to higher-value crops is a gradual but consistent trend<br />

among farmers in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> elsewhere in Vietnam. Between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998, the<br />

share of crop income growth attributable to crop diversification was 8 percent in the rural Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> 17 percent in rural Vietnam. Thus, the government <strong>and</strong> international organizations<br />

working in Vietnam should consider crop diversification to be one important avenue for income<br />

growth, but not the only one. Programs to promote diversification into tea, fruits, medicinal herbs,<br />

<strong>and</strong> other high-value crops have the potential to improve the income <strong>and</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ards of living of rural<br />

households, but this should be an integral part of a broader program to improve the productivity of<br />

rural households. In general, the government should facilitate informed decision-making <strong>and</strong><br />

competitive markets while providing public goods, rather than setting targets for specific commodities<br />

or sectors.<br />

8.2.2 Implications for agricultural research<br />

According to various analyses carried out in this report, yield increases are the most important<br />

source of growth in income from crop production. First, the analysis of the two Vietnam Living<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ards Surveys reveals that yield increases were the most important source of crop income<br />

between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 1998. Second, the review of agricultural statistics indicated that yield growth was<br />

the most important factor in the expansion of rice production in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s over the period<br />

1995-2000. And third, farmers in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s attribute much of their income growth over<br />

the last eight years to higher yields. When our QSAID Household Survey asked rural households in<br />

the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s why their st<strong>and</strong>ard of living had increased, the most common response, cited by<br />

80 percent of the respondents, was higher yields. Thus, agricultural research <strong>and</strong> extension efforts<br />

9<br />

It is true that income growth patterns in the past are not always a good guide for the future. In the<br />

long run, the share of the agricultural sector will shrink <strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> non-farm enterprises will become an important<br />

source of growth. However, structural transformation is a slow process, even in a rapidly growing country like<br />

Vietnam, so growth patterns of the recent past (1990s) are likely to be a good guide for the near future.<br />

Page 188


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

aimed at improving yields is <strong>and</strong> will continue to be the cornerstone of efforts to raise rural incomes<br />

in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. Higher yields may be achieved by various means including higher-yielding<br />

varieties, enhanced disease resistance, better farming practices, improved water control, or better<br />

management of fertilizer <strong>and</strong> other chemicals.<br />

These conclusions are reinforced by recent research on public investment in China <strong>and</strong> India.<br />

Using provincial data on investment, income, <strong>and</strong> poverty in rural China over 1970-1997, Fan et al<br />

(2002) find that investment in agricultural research <strong>and</strong> development had the greatest rate of return<br />

among the six types of investment examined. Each yuan of investment in agricultural research <strong>and</strong><br />

development was estimated to increase rural GDP by 9.6 yuan. The study of India, using a similar<br />

method, found that investment in agricultural research <strong>and</strong> extension had the greatest impact on<br />

productivity growth among the eight types of investment considered (Fan et al, 1999).<br />

We also find that the contribution of crop income growth to overall income growth is greatest<br />

among poor rural households <strong>and</strong> that the contribution of yield increases to crop income growth is<br />

greatest among the poor. Yield increases account for 61 percent of the income growth of the lowest<br />

income category, but only 24 percent of the growth of the highest category. Thus, the rural poor are<br />

much more dependent on yield increases to boost income than other rural households. The policy<br />

implication is that investment in agricultural research <strong>and</strong> extension focused on yield improvement<br />

has a proportionately greater effect on the incomes of the poor than on the incomes of the less poor.<br />

This is because a) the poor are more dependent on crop production <strong>and</strong> b) they are less able to<br />

increase crop income through area expansion or diversification.<br />

These findings are again consistent with the two econometric studies of public investment.<br />

mentioned above. In China, agricultural research ranks second (after rural education) in terms of the<br />

number of people lifted from poverty per yuan of investment (Fan et al, 2002: 45). The povertyreducing<br />

impact was greatest in western China, the least developed of the three regions included in the<br />

analysis. In India, agricultural research was ranked second (after roads) in poverty reduction (Fan et<br />

al, 1999).<br />

Our analysis indicates that improvements in rice yields account for 59 percent of the gains<br />

associated with yield increases <strong>and</strong> 23 percent of the gains in crop income. In the long run, the<br />

importance of rice in farm income may decline, but in the short <strong>and</strong> medium terms, these continue to<br />

be important crops. Thus, agricultural research <strong>and</strong> extension should continue to give priority to<br />

improved varieties of rice (<strong>and</strong> maize to a lesser degree). Although increases in rice yields are<br />

perhaps the largest single contributor to rural income growth, it is important to keep in mind other<br />

factors (price increases, crop diversification, <strong>and</strong> yield increases for other crops) still account for<br />

three-quarters of crop income growth <strong>and</strong> that growth in non-crop activities accounts for over half of<br />

overall income growth.<br />

Page 189


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

8.2.3 Implications for input subsidies<br />

The Qualitative Social Assessment carried out by this project highlighted the key role of the<br />

Ministry of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development <strong>and</strong> its local branches in promoting crop<br />

diversification. Production targets are developed at the central level <strong>and</strong> transmitted to the local<br />

authorities <strong>and</strong> extension agents in the form of production plans. Various means are used to induce<br />

farmers to comply with these plans, including l<strong>and</strong> use restrictions, technical assistance, credit, the<br />

provision of free or subsidized inputs, <strong>and</strong> the establishment of state-owned processing facilities. The<br />

cost of input subsidies in each province seem to range between VND 3 billion <strong>and</strong> 17 billion per year.<br />

The high cost of programs to provide inputs on credit suggest that these programs should be<br />

monitored <strong>and</strong> evaluated on a regular basis to ensure effectiveness. In these evaluations, the costs of<br />

the program, including the subsidies <strong>and</strong> the labor of extension agents <strong>and</strong> others, should be compared<br />

to the benefits of the program in terms of additional income from crop production. The program might<br />

be justified on equity grounds even if the costs exceed the benefits, but the trade-off between equity<br />

<strong>and</strong> cost should be made explicit.<br />

Some subsidization of farmer innovation can be justified on economic grounds. First, because<br />

farmers are risk averse, they will avoid new production technologies even if it pays off on average<br />

(i.e. even if the expected net return is positive). From the point of view of the economy as a whole,<br />

the innovation is worthwhile if the expected net value is positive, so there is a rationale for<br />

subsidizing new technology to compensate for the risk aversion of farmers. Second, because farmers<br />

are cash-constrained <strong>and</strong> credit markets do not function well, farmers may not be able to invest in new<br />

production technologies even if the net return is positive. Thus, there is a second rationale for<br />

subsidizing investments associated with new production technology.<br />

At the same time, even though there is an economic justification for some subsidies for<br />

innovation, this does not mean that any spending to promote new crops is worthwhile. In particular,<br />

these rationales imply three guidelines for subsidizing innovation:<br />

Subsidies on new crops <strong>and</strong> methods should be limited in time. There are economic<br />

justifications for subsidizing the introduction of a new crop, but not for continued subsidies after the<br />

first year (or the first productive year, in the case of tree crops). In other words, providing free seeds<br />

for a new crop is more likely to generate benefits for the economy as a whole than providing a support<br />

price year after year. In particular, the use of import restrictions to raise the domestic price of sugar<br />

<strong>and</strong> sugarcane imposes a net cost on the Vietnamese economy <strong>and</strong> is unlikely to lead to a more<br />

competitive sugar sector (see IFPRI, 1998).<br />

Subsidies on new crops <strong>and</strong> methods should be limited in size. The subsidy should be enough<br />

to offset the risk aversion of farmers, but it should not cover the entire costs of production.. If the<br />

subsidy is too large, then many farmers will participate only to receive the subsidy rather than because<br />

Page 190


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

they hope the technology will be profitable. The result is often a high level of production which only<br />

lasts until the subsidy is withdrawn.<br />

Subsidies should be focused on new crops or new technologies. The idea is to subsidize an<br />

innovation to reduce the element of risk. But there seems to be little justification to subsidizing the<br />

transportation of fertilizer, even if it is targeted toward the poorest communes. It is not a new<br />

technology, so it is hard to argue that there is under-utilization due to risk aversion. Nor is it likely to<br />

be a very effective way of assisting poor farmers. More research in Vietnam may be needed to<br />

quantify the distribution of benefits of this policy, but studies in other countries indicate that fertilizer<br />

subsidies are not an effective means of assisting the poor (see Kherallah et al, 2002). Among other<br />

reasons, fertilizer use is often proportional to farm size, so it is the larger farms with irrigation within<br />

the selected communes that benefit most.<br />

8.2.4 Implications for agricultural extension<br />

The QSAID highlighted both the strengths <strong>and</strong> weaknesses of the extension service. Of those<br />

that received assistance from the extension service, three-quarters said it was useful, <strong>and</strong> of those<br />

adopting new crops, roughly half did so with the encouragement or assistance of an extension agent.<br />

At the same time, less than half the farmers had direct contact with an extension agent. Much of the<br />

dissemination seems to occur indirectly via the village headman or word-of-mouth. In interviews,<br />

local officials identified three weaknesses of the extension service:<br />

• Insufficient number of agents (roughly one per commune).<br />

• Low level of education of extension agents.<br />

• Low salaries <strong>and</strong> job security.<br />

Although this study does not have evidence to claim that the benefits of increasing the number <strong>and</strong><br />

salary of extension agents would be greater than the costs, one option would be to experiment by<br />

apply a more intensive extension effort in selected districts <strong>and</strong> evaluating the results after several<br />

years.<br />

Most of the criticism of the extension service relates to their under-capacity, but sometimes<br />

they are actually too successful. Production campaigns that combine extension effort <strong>and</strong> subsidized<br />

inputs are sometimes so successful in stimulating production that it creates a situation of over-supply<br />

<strong>and</strong> low prices. The QSAID found numerous examples of programs to promote new crops that<br />

succeeded in stimulating production, but failed in raising farmer income because there was “no<br />

market” for the additional output. In some cases, the product characteristics were not suitable for the<br />

intended buyer, often a processor or an exporter. In other cases, the production zone was too far from<br />

the market to make transport worthwhile. Not only do these cases impose losses on small farmers, but<br />

they make farmers more reluctant to participate in future production campaigns. The QSAID surveys<br />

indicate that farmers rarely receive any assistance with marketing new crops <strong>and</strong> that the campaigns<br />

Page 191


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

are focused almost exclusively on production. Furthermore, one-quarter the rural households in our<br />

survey indicated that they had had at least one unsuccessful experience, adopting a new crop only to<br />

ab<strong>and</strong>on it later as unprofitable. Usually, the problem was that there was “no market”, which<br />

generally means that the market price, after deducting the cost of transportation from the producer to<br />

the buyer, is too low to justify continued production.<br />

The implication is that government campaigns to promote new crops need to pay much<br />

greater attention to marketing issues in the selection of crops. Currently, the selection of crops to<br />

promote at the local level seems to be largely determined by provincial <strong>and</strong> central plans for l<strong>and</strong> use<br />

<strong>and</strong> production. These, in turn, are determined by the agro-ecological potential, particularly soil,<br />

temperature, <strong>and</strong> rainfall. To the extent that estimates of the cost of production <strong>and</strong> profitability are<br />

carried, they tend to ignore spatial variation in producer prices associated with transportation costs.<br />

Plans to promote a specific crop in a certain commune should be based on some form of simplified<br />

cost-benefit analysis that takes into account:<br />

• the value of the harvest, taking into account the cost of transporting the output to a<br />

market,<br />

• the expected yield given local soils <strong>and</strong> climate, as well as farmer experience with the<br />

crop,<br />

• the cost of hired labor <strong>and</strong> purchased inputs, including the cost of transporting them to the<br />

farm,<br />

• the requirements in terms of family labor <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> inputs, with some estimate of the<br />

opportunity costs in terms of alternative uses.<br />

• the expected variability in yield <strong>and</strong> market price based on historical experience, <strong>and</strong><br />

• the likely impact on crop prices of a successful campaign to promote the crop.<br />

Such an analysis would be useful for evaluation purposes as well. If the crop turns out not to be<br />

profitable in that area, it would be useful to review the assumptions to determine which was, in<br />

retrospect, overly optimistic. Such feedback would, over time, assist local authorities in improving<br />

their cost-benefit analyses.<br />

The messages delivered by agricultural extension agents also need to include more<br />

information about market conditions. Most farmers report receiving technical assistance, some report<br />

receiving free or subsidized inputs, but very few report getting any information about marketing<br />

conditions. This information is less important if the crop is primarily for home consumption, but<br />

Vietnamese farmers are becoming more <strong>and</strong> more commercialized, even in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

Agricultural extension must adapt to this change by increasing its attention on the market conditions<br />

for crops. When a new crop is being promoted, farmers need to know not just how to plant <strong>and</strong> care<br />

for it, but where the market is, how variable the prices are, what product characteristics are valued by<br />

consumers, <strong>and</strong> so on.<br />

Page 192


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

The background <strong>and</strong> training of most agricultural extension agents is in production<br />

technology. Thus, it is necessary to increase the capacity of agricultural extension agents <strong>and</strong> others<br />

in analyzing agricultural markets, assessing the farm-level profitability of new crops, <strong>and</strong> estimating<br />

the impact of production campaigns on prices. This will involve either recruiting marketing<br />

specialists or providing additional training to existing staff. Given the high ratio of farmers to agents,<br />

it may also involve using voluntary farmer groups (such as cooperatives) to help deliver extension<br />

messages to farmers, gather market information, <strong>and</strong> provide marketing services that have economies<br />

of scale 10 .<br />

8.2.5 Implications for public investment<br />

One of the most difficult questions facing policymakers is how to allocate public investment<br />

among regions <strong>and</strong> sectors. In principal, investment decisions could be made on the basis of a series<br />

of cost-benefit analysis that take into account the distribution of impact across different types of<br />

households. Unfortunately, by their very nature, most public investments generate benefits that<br />

extend over many years <strong>and</strong> are widely distributed among the population.<br />

This study does not examine the actual returns to alternative public investment, but it does<br />

have some results that shed light on the issue. The social accounting analysis suggests that the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s has an advantage in the cost of production for many commodities, but the large<br />

marketing margins offset this competitive advantage. The implication is that investment in roads in<br />

the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s would provide a significant boost to agricultural production <strong>and</strong> rural incomes.<br />

In addition, the QSAID examined the priorities of rural households regarding public<br />

investment choices. Among the public investment alternatives 11 , rural households in the QSAID<br />

survey ranked “better support for existing crops” as the highest priority. This response probably<br />

implies an interest in agricultural research <strong>and</strong> extension services, though other “support,” such as<br />

market information, may also be implied. Roads, irrigation, <strong>and</strong> promotion of new crops were next,<br />

all having a similar rating. Better education <strong>and</strong> health care, electrification, <strong>and</strong> clean water were<br />

ranked much lower by the respondents in the survey. Thus, according to the stated preferences of<br />

rural households, the government should give priority to investments to support existing crops,<br />

promote new crops, irrigation, <strong>and</strong> rural roads, in that order.<br />

Of course, there are limitations to this type of inquiry. It is not clear if respondents are<br />

comparing the value of public investments of similar value. For example, they may be mentally<br />

comparing a new paved road to the village with a new village water pump, ignoring the fact that the<br />

road would require a much larger investment. Nonetheless, the results are roughly consistent with<br />

10<br />

“Economies of scale” describes activities whose per unit costs fall if they are carried out in large<br />

volumes. For example, processing <strong>and</strong> transport are often less costly per kilogram if done on a larger scale.<br />

11 The question asked more broadly about the most useful types of government assistance. “Better<br />

access to credit” was cited most often by our respondents. Although this has implications for the development<br />

of the financial sector, it is not directly related to public investment priorities.<br />

Page 193


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

econometric analysis of public investments. In the studies of India <strong>and</strong> China mentioned above, the<br />

three types of public investment with the greatest impact on income <strong>and</strong> poverty reduction were<br />

agricultural research <strong>and</strong> extension, roads, <strong>and</strong> rural education (see Fan et al, 1999 <strong>and</strong> 2002).<br />

Another finding from the QSAID is that the priorities of rural households in the Northern<br />

Upl<strong>and</strong>s vary by location. Based on the stated priorities of rural households, public investment<br />

should give greater weight to roads, electrification, <strong>and</strong> clean water in the more remote areas of the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. Presumably, this reflects the fact that households in the lowl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> near major<br />

roads already have good infrastructure <strong>and</strong> so their priorities for government assistance are elsewhere.<br />

Even in remote areas, however, support for existing crops is given the highest priority by rural<br />

households.<br />

8.2.6 Implications for credit policy<br />

The QSAID Household Survey asks respondents about the most useful forms of government<br />

intervention. Better access to credit is the most common response, cited by two-thirds of the<br />

respondents. This is a common finding in surveys of rural households throughout the developing<br />

world, <strong>and</strong> “better access to credit” is one of the most common recommendations made to<br />

governments by applied researchers. But the issue is complex. First, it is difficult to know whether<br />

rural households would like better access to credit at market interest rates or if it is a request for<br />

subsidized credit. Since subsidized credit <strong>and</strong> loan forgiveness are often used by governments to<br />

transfer resources to households, sometimes for political purposes, it would not be surprising if the<br />

QSAID responses reflected an interest in subsidized credit.<br />

Second, even if rural households really would like better access at market rates, there is not<br />

obvious <strong>and</strong> easy strategy for the government to “improve access.” Anecdotal evidence collected by<br />

the QSAID suggests that lending money is risky. The interviews with local officials reveal examples<br />

of credit programs with low repayment rates. Officials claim that households often borrow with the<br />

stated intention of investing in productive capacity, but the loans may actually be used for<br />

consumption purposes, such as weddings or funerals. Furthermore, the allocation of credit is<br />

sometimes subject to corruption, in which borrowers pay bribes to receive loans or to avoid<br />

repayment. The interviews with traders indicate that they are very reluctant to offer credit to farmers<br />

<strong>and</strong> almost always operate on a cash basis. The few traders that offer credit admit to having problems<br />

with repayment.<br />

The Vietnam Bank for Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development is the main formal source of credit<br />

for the agricultural sector. It has close to 1500 branches <strong>and</strong> employs over 20,000 people, but small<br />

farmers complain that the procedures are too complicated <strong>and</strong> the interest rates too high. The<br />

VBARD has recently tried to make credit available in smaller amounts with lower transaction costs,<br />

often with support from international organizations. The Vietnam Bank for the Poor (VBP) was<br />

formed in 1996 to engage in micro-finance, lending small amounts to poor households. The lending<br />

Page 194


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

interest rates are lower, but the VBP relies heavily on subsidies from government <strong>and</strong> funding from<br />

international organizations. And the People’s Credit Fund (PCF) is a new approach involving<br />

decentralized credit unions with local participation in decisions. The network of PCFs has grown<br />

rapidly over the last five years.<br />

This study did not directly address the issue of rural credit, so we cannot provide<br />

recommendations. International experience, however, suggests a number of guidelines for the<br />

development of a financial sector that can better serve rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong><br />

elsewhere:<br />

• Lowering the transaction costs of borrowing is more than lowering interest rates in terms<br />

of improving access to credit for small farmers.<br />

• The bulk of potential borrowers are interested in relatively small loans, so it is necessary<br />

to develop institutional arrangements that reduce the cost of approving, monitoring, <strong>and</strong><br />

recovering loans.<br />

• Developing low-cost methods of gathering information on the credit-worthiness of<br />

potential borrowers <strong>and</strong> enforcing repayment is critical to the success of such schemes.<br />

• Group-based lending (where a self-selected group of borrowers takes joint responsibility<br />

for repayment) is one institutional arrangement with the potential for reducing transaction<br />

costs <strong>and</strong> motivating repayment.<br />

• Graduated lending (in which loans are initially small, but repayment opens the door to<br />

larger loans) is another strategy for reducing the risk of non-repayment while acquiring<br />

information about the credit-worthiness of borrowers.<br />

• Sustainability requires that greater emphasis be placed on mobilizing rural savings instead<br />

of channeling funds from the government <strong>and</strong> international organizations.<br />

Currently, there are various programs to offer subsidies on productive agricultural investment.<br />

Farmers are offered cash for terracing; seedlings <strong>and</strong> other inputs for tree crops are provided free or at<br />

subsidized prices. Investment subsidies may be necessary in the medium term, but subsidies on<br />

investment should be considered a second-best solution to improving credit markets.<br />

8.2.7 Implications for livestock development<br />

This study finds contradictory evidence regarding livestock development. According to the<br />

analysis of the VLSS, livestock activities contributed 9-13 percent of overall income of rural<br />

households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> 8 percent of the income growth over 1993-98. And yet,<br />

when the QSAID asked households the reasons for the growth in their income since 1994, 62 percent<br />

cited livestock income as one of the three most important causes (only “higher yields” was cited more<br />

often). And 72 percent agreed that livestock <strong>and</strong> aquaculture development are good ways to help the<br />

poor increase their income. There are three possible reasons for this discrepancy:<br />

• perhaps livestock development has taken off in recent years, so it was recorded by the<br />

QSAID in 2002 but not the VLSS in 1998<br />

Page 195


Chapter 8. Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusions<br />

• perhaps the growth in livestock income is under-estimated by the VLSS, which is<br />

plausible given the fact that livestock income is dominated by large, infrequent<br />

transactions, implying a margin of error that is larger than for other types of income<br />

• perhaps the QSAID results are not representative, either because of the small sample size<br />

or because households over-estimate the contribution of livestock to their income growth.<br />

In any case, the dem<strong>and</strong> analysis indicates that the consumption of meat <strong>and</strong> other animal<br />

products will rise rapidly as incomes grow. At the same time, large-scale production of animals,<br />

particularly poultry, is taking off. The real question is the degree to which small farmers in the<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s will be able to participate in the growing livestock sector or whether they will be<br />

squeezed out by industrial operations. The implication is that the government should study<br />

institutional mechanisms for involving small farmers in livestock production for urban markets.<br />

Based on the experience of other developing countries, one promising approach is contract farming<br />

arrangements for poultry production (Delgado et al, 1999).<br />

8.2.8 Implications for promoting non-farm employment<br />

The share of income from non-farm enterprises tends to be greater among higher-income rural<br />

households. Therefore, programs to develop existing non-farm rural enterprises will probably<br />

directly assist higher-income households more than the poor. To the extent that the existing patterns<br />

reflect some inherent advantage of higher-income households in managing non-farm enterprises (such<br />

as greater tolerance of risk or greater liquidity), it may be difficult to assist poorer households start<br />

enterprises. Furthermore, few rural households in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s believe that non-farm<br />

enterprises are a promising approach to helping poor rural households. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, promoting<br />

the development of non-farm rural enterprises may promote regional growth <strong>and</strong> could have indirect<br />

benefits for the poor by increasing the efficiency <strong>and</strong> competition in services they use, such as rice<br />

milling, agricultural trade, or repair services.<br />

The analysis of the VLSS data indicate that the non-farm enterprise sector is very diverse.<br />

Even a broad category such as food processing accounts for less than one quarter of the enterprises in<br />

the rural Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s. One implication of this heterogeneity is that sector-specific technical<br />

assistance will have a potential audience that would be small compared to (for example) growers of<br />

rice or maize. Thus, providing technical assistance to non-farm enterprises would be difficult because<br />

of the extreme heterogeneity of the sector.<br />

Even though it is costly to provide technical assistance to specific types of non-farm<br />

enterprises, the sector as a whole can be promoted by creating a supportive environment. In other<br />

words, the promotion of non-farm enterprises is best done through policies <strong>and</strong> regulations that assist<br />

the sector as a whole. This would include simplifying the registration process, avoiding unnecessary<br />

regulations, making tax policy fair <strong>and</strong> transparent, <strong>and</strong> improving the access to credit for small<br />

enterprises.<br />

Page 196


REFERENCES<br />

Page 199


References<br />

Page 200


References<br />

Alther, C., J.C. Castella, P. Novosad, E. Rouseau, <strong>and</strong> Tran Trong Hieu. 2002. “Impact of<br />

accessibility on the range of livelihood options available to farm households in mountainous<br />

areas of northern Viet Nam.” In Castella, J.C. <strong>and</strong> Dang Dinh Quang (eds.). Doi Moi in the<br />

Mountains: L<strong>and</strong> use changes <strong>and</strong> farmers’ livelihood strategies in Bac Kan Province, Viet<br />

Nam. Agricultural Publishing House. Hanoi.<br />

Arndt, C., A. Cruz, H. T. Jensen, S. Robinson <strong>and</strong> F. Tarp 1998. “Social Accounting Matrices for<br />

Mozambique: 1994-95.” Discussion Paper No. 28, Trade <strong>and</strong> Macroeconomics Division,<br />

International Food Policy Research Institute. Washington, D.C.<br />

Bacharach, M.O.L. 1970. Biproportionate Matrices <strong>and</strong> Input-Output Change. Cambridge<br />

University Press, Cambridge.<br />

Bales, S. 2000. “Vietnams Labor Situation <strong>and</strong> Trends: Analysis based on the 1992-93 <strong>and</strong> 1997-98<br />

Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey.” Background Paper for the Vietnam Development Report<br />

2000, World Bank, Hanoi.<br />

Barrett, C., M. Bezuneh, <strong>and</strong> A. Aboud. 2001. “<strong>Income</strong> diversification, poverty traps, <strong>and</strong> policy<br />

shocks in Cote d’Ivoire <strong>and</strong> Kenya.” Food Policy 26: 367-384.<br />

Barrett, C., M. Bezuneh, D. Clay, <strong>and</strong> T. Reardon. 2000. “Heterogeneous constraints, incentives, <strong>and</strong><br />

income diversification strategies in rural Africa.” Broadening Access <strong>and</strong> Strengthening<br />

Input Market Systems. University of Wisconsin, Madison, Wisconsin.<br />

Bautista, R. 2000. “Agriculture-Based Development: A SAM Perspective on Central Viet Nam.”<br />

Discussion Paper No. 51, Trade <strong>and</strong> Macroeconomics Division. International Food Policy<br />

Research Institute. Washington, D.C.<br />

Block, S. <strong>and</strong> P. Webb. 2001. “The dynamics of livelihood diversification in post-famine Ethiopia.”<br />

Food Policy 26: 333-350.<br />

Castella, J.C. <strong>and</strong> Dang Dinh Quang (eds.). 2002. Doi Moi in the Mountains: L<strong>and</strong> use changes <strong>and</strong><br />

farmers’ livelihood strategies in Bac Kan Province, Viet Nam. Agricultural Publishing House.<br />

Hanoi.<br />

Castella, J.C., Tran Quoc Hoa, O. Husson, Vu Hai Nam, <strong>and</strong> Dang Dinh Quang. 2000. “The declining<br />

role of ethnicity in farm household differentiation: A case study from Ngoc Phai Commune,<br />

Cho Don District, Bac Kan Province, Viet Nam.” In Castella, J.C. <strong>and</strong> Dang Dinh Quang<br />

(eds.). Doi Moi in the Mountains: L<strong>and</strong> use changes <strong>and</strong> farmers’ livelihood strategies in Bac<br />

Kan Province, Viet Nam. Agricultural Publishing House. Hanoi.<br />

CIEM 2000. National Accounting Framework <strong>and</strong> a Macroeconometric Model for Vietnam. Central<br />

Institute for Economic Management, Hanoi.<br />

Delgado, C. <strong>and</strong> A. Siamwalla. 1997. “Rural economy <strong>and</strong> farm income diversification in developing<br />

countries.” Discussion Paper No. 20. Markets <strong>and</strong> Structural Studies Division. International<br />

Food Policy Research Institute. Washington, D.C.<br />

Delgado, C., M. Rosegrant, H. Steinfeld, S. Ehui, <strong>and</strong> C. Courbois. 1999. Livestock to 2020: The next<br />

food revolution. 2020 Vision Discussion Paper No. 28. International Food Policy Research<br />

Institute. Washington, D.C.<br />

Dervis, K., J. de Melo, <strong>and</strong> S. Robinson 1982. General Equilibrium Models for Development Policy.<br />

Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.<br />

Ersado, L. 2003. “<strong>Income</strong> diversification in Zimbabwe: Welfare implications from urban <strong>and</strong> rural<br />

areas.” Food Consumption <strong>and</strong> Nutrition Division Discussion Paper No. 152. International<br />

Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C.<br />

Page 201


References<br />

Escobal, J. 2001. “The determinants of nonfarm income diversification in rural Peru.” World<br />

Development 29 (3): 497-508.<br />

Fan, S., L. Zhang, <strong>and</strong> X. Zhang. 2002. Growth, inequality, <strong>and</strong> poverty in rural China: The role of<br />

public investments. Research Report No. 125. International Food Policy Research Institute.<br />

Washington, D.C.<br />

Fatoux, C., J.C. Castella, M. Zeiss, <strong>and</strong> Pham Hung Manh. 2002. “From rice cultivator to agroforester<br />

within a decade: The impact of Doi Moi on agricultural diversification in a mountainous<br />

commune of Choi Moi District, BacKan Province, Viet Nam.” In Castella, J.C. <strong>and</strong> Dang<br />

Dinh Quang (eds.). Doi Moi in the Mountains: L<strong>and</strong> use changes <strong>and</strong> farmers’ livelihood<br />

strategies in Bac Kan Province, Viet Nam. Agricultural Publishing House. Hanoi.<br />

Fan, S., P. Hazell, <strong>and</strong> S. Thorat. 1999. Linkages between government spending, growth, <strong>and</strong> poverty<br />

in rural India. Research Report No. 110. International Food Policy Research Institute.<br />

Washington, D.C.<br />

General Statistical Office. 1997. Statistical Yearbook 1996. Statistical Publishing House, Hanoi.<br />

General Statistical Office. 1998. Major social <strong>and</strong> economic information obtained from the largescale<br />

surveys in period of 1990-1996. Statistical Publishing House. Hanoi.<br />

General Statistical Office. 1999. Input-Output Tables for Vietnam. General Statistics Office, Hanoi.<br />

General Statistical Office. 2000a. Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey 1997-1998. Statistical Publishing<br />

House, Hanoi.<br />

General Statistical Office. 2000b. Results of the Household’s Living St<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>and</strong> Economic<br />

Conditions Survey in 1999. Statistical Publishing House. Hanoi.<br />

General Statistical Office. 2001a. Socio-Economic Statistical Data of 61 Provinces <strong>and</strong> Cities in<br />

Vietnam. General Statistical Office, Integrated Statistics <strong>and</strong> Information Department.<br />

Statistical Publishing House, Hanoi.<br />

General Statistical Office. 2001b. The System of National Accounts for Vietnam. General Statistical<br />

Office, Hanoi.<br />

General Statistical Office. 2002b. “Regional Macroeconomic Data for 2000 Provided to Supplement<br />

The System of National Accounts for Vietnam.” Mimeo, General Statistical Office, Hanoi.<br />

Goletti, F. <strong>and</strong> K. Rich.1998. Policy simulation for agricultural diversification. Prepared for the<br />

United Nations Development Programme, UNDP VIE/96/008/A/01/99, “Strengthening<br />

Capacity for the Renewal for Rural Development in Vietnam, Phase 1.” Prepared by the<br />

International Food Policy Research Institute. Washington, D.C.<br />

Henin, B. 2002. “Agrarian change in Vietnam’s northern upl<strong>and</strong> region.” Journal of Contemporary<br />

Asia. 32 (1): 3-28.<br />

Huong, L. 2002. “Impacts of Trade <strong>and</strong> Investment Policy on <strong>Income</strong> Distribution in Vietnam Using a<br />

General Equilibrium Framework.” MSc. Thesis. Australian National University, Canberra.<br />

IMF 2001. Vietnam Government Revenues 1997 - 2001, Mimeo, International Monetary Fund,<br />

Hanoi.<br />

Joint Working Group. 2000. Vietnam Development Report 2000: Attacking <strong>Poverty</strong>. Joint report of<br />

the Government-Donor-NGO Working Group. Hanoi, Vietnam.<br />

Joshi, P.K, A. Gulati, P.S. Birthal, <strong>and</strong> L. Twari. 2003. “Agricultural diversification in South Asia:<br />

Patterns, determinants, <strong>and</strong> policy implications.” Markets, Trade, <strong>and</strong> Institutions Division<br />

Discussion Paper No 57.. International Food Policy Research Institute. Washington, D.C.<br />

Kherallah, M., C. Delgado, E. Gabre-Madhin, N. Minot. <strong>and</strong> M. Johnson. 2002. Reforming<br />

Agricultural Markets in Africa. Johns Hopkins University Press. Baltimore.<br />

Page 202


References<br />

King, B.B. 1985. “What Is a SAM” in G. Pyatt <strong>and</strong> J.I. Round, Social Accounting Matrices: A Basis<br />

for Planning. The World Bank, Washington, D.C.<br />

Kurosaki, T. 2003. “Specialization <strong>and</strong> diversification in agricultural transformation: The case of<br />

West Punjab, 1903-1992.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 85 (2) (May): 372-<br />

386.<br />

Lanjouw, J. <strong>and</strong> P. Lanjouw. 2001. “The rural non-farm sector: Issues <strong>and</strong> evidence from developing<br />

countries.” Agricultural Economics 26: 1-13.<br />

Ministry of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development. Statistics of Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Rural Development<br />

1996-2000. Department of Planning <strong>and</strong> Projection. Agricultural Publishing House, Hanoi.<br />

Ministry of Labor, Invalids, <strong>and</strong> Social Affairs (MOLISA). 2001. TËp bn ®å "Phô cÊp khu vùc"<br />

®Þa bµn hµnh chÝnh x· (Atlas "Regional Government Allowances at the Commune<br />

Administrative Level"). Cartographic Publishing House. Hanoi.<br />

Minot, N. 2000. “Generating disaggregated poverty maps: An application to Vietnam.” World<br />

Development 28 (2): 319-331.<br />

Minot, N. <strong>and</strong> B. Baulch. 2002. “The Spatial Distribution of <strong>Poverty</strong> in Vietnam <strong>and</strong> the Potential for<br />

Targeting.” Discussion Paper No. 43. Markets <strong>and</strong> Structural Studies Division. International<br />

Food Policy Research Institute. Washington, D.C. (47 pages) Also forthcoming as Chapter 7<br />

in David Dollar <strong>and</strong> Paul Glewwe (eds.) Economic growth <strong>and</strong> household welfare in Vietnam<br />

in the 1990s. The World Bank. Washington, D.C.<br />

Minot, N. <strong>and</strong> F. Goletti. 1998. “Rice export liberalization <strong>and</strong> welfare in Vietnam.” American<br />

Journal of Agricultural Economics. 80 (4): 738-749.<br />

Minot, N. <strong>and</strong> F. Goletti. 2000. Rice Market Liberalization <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> in Viet Nam. Research Report<br />

No. 114. International Food Policy Research Institute. Washington, DC. (see<br />

http://www.ifpri.org/pubs/abstract/abstr114.htm)<br />

Nguyen Trong Dieu. 1995. Geography of Vietnam. The Gioi Publishers. Hanoi.<br />

Pederson, G. <strong>and</strong> M. Annou. 1999. “Rural household income diversification in Viet Nam.” Quarterly<br />

Journal of International Agriculture. 2.<br />

Pingali, P. <strong>and</strong> M. Rosegrant. 1995. “Agricultural commercialization <strong>and</strong> diversification: Process <strong>and</strong><br />

policies.” Food Policy 20 (3): 171-185.<br />

Pyatt, G. <strong>and</strong> J. Round (eds.) 1985. Social Accounting Matrices: A Basis for Planning. The World<br />

Bank, Washington, D.C.<br />

Quiroz, J.A. <strong>and</strong> A. Valdes. 1995. “Agricultural diversification <strong>and</strong> policy reform.” Food Policy 20:<br />

245-255.<br />

Reardon, T. 1997. “Using evidence of household income diversification to inform the study of rural<br />

nonfarm labor market in Africa.” World Development 25 (5): 735-747.<br />

Reinert, K.A., <strong>and</strong> D. Rol<strong>and</strong>-Holst 1997. “Social Accounting Matrices.” in J.F. Francois <strong>and</strong> K.A.<br />

Reinert (eds.). Applied Methods for Trade Policy Analysis. Cambridge Universtiy,<br />

Cambridge.<br />

Robinson, Sherman <strong>and</strong> Moataz El-Said 2000. “GAMS Code for Estimating a Social Accounting<br />

Matrix (SAM) Using Cross-Entropy (C-E) Methods.” Discussion Paper No. 64. Trade <strong>and</strong><br />

Macroeconomics Division. International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C.<br />

Robinson, Sherman, Andrea Cattaneo <strong>and</strong> Moataz El-Said 1998. “Estimating a Social Accounting<br />

Matrix Using Entropy Methods” Discussion Paper No. 33. Trade <strong>and</strong> Macroeconomics<br />

Division, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C.<br />

State Planning Commission/General Statistics Office. 1994. Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey 1992-<br />

93. State Planning Committee <strong>and</strong> General Statistics Office. Hanoi.<br />

Page 203


References<br />

Stone, R. 1981. Aspects of Economic <strong>and</strong> Social Modeling, No. 126, Librairie Druz, Geneva.<br />

Tarp, F., D. Rol<strong>and</strong>-Holst, J. R<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> H.T. Jensen 2002. “A Social Accounting Matrix for Vietnam<br />

for the Year 2000”, Mimeo, Central Institute for Economic Management. Hanoi.<br />

Tarp, Finn <strong>and</strong> David Rol<strong>and</strong>-Holst 2002. “Household income determination in Vietnam: A structural<br />

analysis with implications for market reform.” Discussion Paper DP0203, Central Institute of<br />

Economic Management, Hanoi, <strong>and</strong> Nordic Institute of Asian Studies, Copenhagen, 2002.<br />

(see http://eurasia.nias.ku.dk/Gems/CIEMNIAS/DP0203.pdf).<br />

Tarp, Finn, David Rol<strong>and</strong>-Holst, <strong>and</strong> John R<strong>and</strong>. 2002. “Economic Structure <strong>and</strong> Development in an<br />

Emergent Asian Economy: Evidence from a Social Accounting Matrix for Vietnam.”<br />

Discussion Paper DP0202. Central Institute of Economic Management, Hanoi, <strong>and</strong> Nordic<br />

Institute of Asian Studies, Copenhagen, 2002. (see http://eurasia.nias.ku.dk/Gems<br />

/CIEMNIAS /DP0202.pdf).<br />

Tarp, Finn, David Rol<strong>and</strong>-Holst, <strong>and</strong> John R<strong>and</strong>. 2002. “Trade <strong>and</strong> <strong>Income</strong> Growth in Vietnam:<br />

Estimates from a New Social Accounting Matrix.” Discussion Paper DP0201. Central<br />

Institute of Economic Management, Hanoi, <strong>and</strong> Nordic Institute of Asian Studies,<br />

Copenhagen. (see http://eurasia.nias.ku.dk/Gems/CIEMNIAS/DP0201.pdf).<br />

Tarp, Finn, David Rol<strong>and</strong>-Holst, John R<strong>and</strong>, Pham Lan Huong, Vo Tri Thanh, Pham Hoang Ha <strong>and</strong><br />

Do Thi Thu Huong. 2001. A 1999 Social Accounting Matrix for Vietnam. The Gioi<br />

Publishers. Hanoi. (see http://eurasia.nias.ku.dk/CIEMNIAS/stories/storyReader$9).<br />

United Nations (undated), Social Accounting Matrix Based Macromodels for Policy Analysis in<br />

Developing Countries, United Nations, New York.<br />

United Nations Statistical Office (UNSO) 1968. A System of National Accounts, United Nations, New<br />

York.<br />

United Nations Statistical Office (UNSO) 2001. COMTRADE Bilateral Direction of Trade Statistics,<br />

United Nations, New York.<br />

United States Geological Survey. 2003. GTOPO30 Database, Tile E1000N40. Downloaded from<br />

http://edcdaac.usgs.gov/gtopo30/gtopo30.html.<br />

Vu Nang Dung (editor). 2001. Nong nghiep Viet Nam 61 tinh va thanh pho. [Vietnamese Agriculture<br />

in 61 Provinces <strong>and</strong> Cities]. National Institute for Agricultural Planning <strong>and</strong> Projection.<br />

Agricultural Publishing House, Hanoi.<br />

World Bank. 2000. Entering the 21 st Century – World Development Report 1999-2000. The World<br />

Bank. Oxford University Press. New York, NY.<br />

Page 204


GLOSSARY<br />

Page 205


Glossary<br />

Page 206


Glossary<br />

close-ended questions: questions in an interview for which all the possible answers have been<br />

specified <strong>and</strong> assigned a code before the survey begins (see open-ended questions).<br />

crop income: income earned from the production of annual <strong>and</strong> perennial crops, but excluding<br />

forestry. Crop income includes both the cash income from the sale of crops <strong>and</strong> the in-kind<br />

income from the consumption or household use of crop products.<br />

coefficient: in regression analysis, the coefficient associated with an independent variable is the effect<br />

of a one unit change in that variable on the dependent variable (see regression analysis).<br />

commercialization: the process of increasing the share of income that is earned in cash (e.g. wage<br />

income) <strong>and</strong> reducing the share that is earned in kind (e.g. growing food for consumption by<br />

the same household).<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> analysis: a study of the factors that influence the consumption of different goods <strong>and</strong> services<br />

as a function of prices, household income, <strong>and</strong> other household characteristics using<br />

regression analysis. See Chapter 4 for more information.<br />

diversity: a measure of the number of different categories in a population <strong>and</strong> the similarity of the<br />

size of the different categories. For example, a household with high level of diversity in its<br />

income sources is one with a large number of income sources that are all similar in size. (see<br />

Simpson index of diversity <strong>and</strong> Shannon-Weaver index of diversity)<br />

elasticity: The percentage change in one variable in response to a one percent change in another<br />

variable (see price elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong>, income elasticity, <strong>and</strong> supply elasticity).<br />

enterprise income: income earned from self-employment in a small business, including retail trading,<br />

wholesale trading, rice milling, repair work, tailoring, construction, or professional services.<br />

fishery income: income earned from raising or catching fish or seafood, whether the product is sold<br />

or consumed by the household.<br />

forestry income: income earned from the production of firewood, construction materials, <strong>and</strong> other<br />

products from forests, including both natural <strong>and</strong> planted forest <strong>and</strong> including both sales <strong>and</strong><br />

home consumption.<br />

Hicksian price elasticity: the ratio indicating the percentage change in dem<strong>and</strong> resulting from a one<br />

percent change in the price, holding household utility constant. This is also called the<br />

compensated price elasticity because the consumer is being compensated for the effect of the<br />

price change price on purchasing power (see price elasticity).<br />

high-value agricultural commodities: commodities that have a high value per kilogram or that<br />

generate high returns per hectare or per day of labor. Fruits, vegetables, spices, specialty<br />

crops, meat, dairy, <strong>and</strong> fish are often considered high-value agricultural commodities.<br />

income elasticity: a ratio that indicates the percentage change in dem<strong>and</strong> for a product as a result of a<br />

one percent increase in household income See Chapter 4 for more information.<br />

informal interview: an interview in which the general topics are defined before the interview, but the<br />

exact questions have not been defined<br />

livestock income: income from raising animals (including cattle, buffalo, pigs, poultry, <strong>and</strong> reptiles)<br />

<strong>and</strong> selling animal products (including meat, eggs, honey, <strong>and</strong> dairy products). Livestock<br />

income includes both the cash income from livestock product sales <strong>and</strong> the in-kind income<br />

from the use or consumption of livestock products by the household.<br />

Page 207


Marshallian price elasticity: the ratio indicating the percentage change in dem<strong>and</strong> resulting from a<br />

one percent change in the price, holding income constant. This is also called the<br />

uncompensated price elasticity because the consumer is not being compensated for the effect<br />

of the change in price (see price elasticity).<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong>s: the 14 provinces that constitute the Northwest <strong>and</strong> Northeast regions of Vietnam<br />

open-ended questions: questions in an interview for which the possible answers have not been<br />

specified nor assigned a code before the survey begins (see closed-ended questions).<br />

price elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong>: a ratio that indicates the percentage change in dem<strong>and</strong> for a product as a<br />

result of a one percent increase in a price. The own-price elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong> is the<br />

percentage change in dem<strong>and</strong> for a product as a result of a one percent increase in the price of<br />

the same product. Unless otherwise specified, the price elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong> is assumed to be<br />

the own-price elasticity. See Chapter 4 for more information.<br />

purposive sampling: selecting a sample using human judgment in an attempt to make it representative<br />

of the larger population in terms of specific variables. This method is often used in small<br />

samples where the researcher has some knowledge of the characteristics of the population<br />

(see r<strong>and</strong>om sample).<br />

qualitative social assessment: an evaluation of some aspect of living st<strong>and</strong>ards, well-being, or social<br />

conditions that is based on interviews that include at least some open-ended questions <strong>and</strong>/or<br />

non-survey methods of data collection.<br />

quintile: a group of 20 percent of the total population, created by sorting the population by some<br />

variable <strong>and</strong> then dividing it into five equal-sized groups. For example, the poorest income<br />

quintile refers to the poorest 20 percent of the population (see tercile).<br />

r<strong>and</strong>om sampling: selecting a sample using r<strong>and</strong>om numbers, where the researcher determines the<br />

method (stratification, clustering, sample size, etc.) but is not involved in the selection process<br />

itself (see purposive sampling).<br />

regression analysis: a statistical method that identifies the mathematical equation that best describes<br />

the relationship between one dependent variable <strong>and</strong> various independent variables (see<br />

coefficient, dem<strong>and</strong> analysis, <strong>and</strong> supply response analysis).<br />

semi-structured interview: an interview in which some of the questions to be asked were defined<br />

before the interview but others are not, so that the interviews have some questions in common<br />

<strong>and</strong> others different (see structured interview).<br />

Shannon-Weaver index of diversity: a measure of diversity, similar to the Simpson index of diversity.<br />

The equation for the Shannon-Weaver index is provided in Section 3.2.3 of this report (see<br />

diversity).<br />

Simpson index of diversity: a measure of diversity, equal to one minus the probably that two<br />

r<strong>and</strong>omly selected elements will be in the same category. The equation for the Simpson index<br />

is provided in Section 3.2.3 of this report (see diversity).<br />

social accounting matrix: a table showing the flow of money <strong>and</strong> goods among industries,<br />

households, the government, <strong>and</strong> the rest of the world. Each industry, household type, or<br />

other account is represented by a row <strong>and</strong> by a column, <strong>and</strong> each cell represents the flow of<br />

money from the column account to the row account. More information is provided in Chapter<br />

7 of this report.<br />

structured interview: an interview in which the exact questions to be asked <strong>and</strong> the order of the<br />

questions has been defined before the interview, so that all interviews have the same<br />

questions (see semi-structured interview).<br />

supply response analysis: an analysis of the factors that influence the production of goods or services<br />

in terms of producer prices, input prices, <strong>and</strong> the types of fixed assets (such as l<strong>and</strong>)<br />

controlled by the producer. Regression analysis is used to estimate the effect of each factor<br />

Page 208


Glossary<br />

on production. More information is provided in Appendix A. (see regression analysis <strong>and</strong><br />

supply elasticity).<br />

supply elasticity: a ratio of the percentage increase in production associated with a one percent<br />

increase in the price of a good. The own-price supply elasticity is the percentage increase in<br />

production associated with a one percent increase in the price of the same good. Unless<br />

otherwise specified, the supply elasticity is assumed to be the own-price supply elasticity.<br />

More information is provided in Appendix A (see supply response analysis).<br />

tercile: A group of about 33 percent of the total population, created by sorting the population by some<br />

variable <strong>and</strong> then dividing it into three equal-sized groups. For example, the richest tercile of<br />

per capita income refers to households among the richest 33% of the population (see quintile).<br />

transfer income: income obtained from an individual, from the government, or from a nongovernmental<br />

organization that is not in exchange for goods or services provided by<br />

household members. This includes gifts, remittances, <strong>and</strong> other private transfers as well as<br />

assistance provided through anti-poverty programs.<br />

wage income: income earned by selling labor on a per-hour or per-day basis, including agricultural<br />

labor, teaching, government employment, <strong>and</strong> employment in a private enterprise.<br />

Page 209


Page 210


Appendix A:<br />

Results of the analysis of the determinants of agricultural supply<br />

Page 211


Appendix A: Supply response analysis<br />

Page 212


Appendix A: Supply response analysis<br />

This section describes the results of an analysis of agricultural supply elasticity using the<br />

1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey. The results are not included in the body of the report<br />

because, in the end, the findings were not very credible <strong>and</strong> do not contribute to the other components<br />

of the report.<br />

1 Method<br />

The supply analysis adopted the profit function approach, which integrates econometric<br />

estimation of output supply <strong>and</strong> input dem<strong>and</strong>. Under certain conditions, the behavior of a rational<br />

profit-maximizing producer can be described by a restricted profit function of the form:<br />

π = f ( p,<br />

z)<br />

where π is the return on fixed factors of production, p is a vector of the prices of output(s)<br />

<strong>and</strong> variable inputs, <strong>and</strong> z is a vector of fixed factors of production. This is a restricted profit function<br />

in that it is assumed that the producer can decide on the levels of variable inputs but cannot change the<br />

levels of the fixed factors. Thus, it describes a planning horizon of 1-3 years.<br />

If we define q as a vector describing the output supply <strong>and</strong> the negative of input dem<strong>and</strong>, then<br />

according to production theory, the first derivative of the profit function with respect to the price of an<br />

input (or output) yields input dem<strong>and</strong> (or output supply):<br />

∂π(<br />

p,<br />

z)<br />

q<br />

i<br />

( p,<br />

z)<br />

=<br />

p<br />

i<br />

Young's Theorem states that the cross-partial second derivatives of a function are equal to<br />

each other. Applying this rule to the profit function, we get:<br />

2<br />

∂q<br />

i<br />

( p,<br />

z)<br />

∂ π(<br />

p,<br />

z)<br />

∂q<br />

j(<br />

p,<br />

z)<br />

= =<br />

∂p<br />

∂q<br />

∂q<br />

∂p<br />

j<br />

i<br />

j<br />

i<br />

To take a concrete example, this means that the effect of a one-unit change in the price of<br />

fertilizer on rice supply must be the same as the effect of a one-unit change in the price of rice on<br />

(negative) fertilizer dem<strong>and</strong>. These symmetry restrictions are useful in applied econometric work<br />

because they improve the efficiency of econometric estimation. Furthermore, they ensure that the<br />

parameter estimates obtained are consistent with economic theory.<br />

In order to make use of these restrictions, we use Zellner's seemingly unrelated regression<br />

(SUR) with cross-equation restrictions to ensure symmetry of price effects. We use the normalized<br />

quadratic profit function:<br />

* 1<br />

* *<br />

*<br />

π*<br />

= a<br />

0<br />

+ ∑ a<br />

ip<br />

+ ∑ ∑ bijp<br />

p + ∑ ∑c<br />

i<br />

i j<br />

ikpi<br />

z<br />

2<br />

i<br />

i<br />

j<br />

where the asterisks indicate that profits <strong>and</strong> prices have been normalized by dividing by the numeraire<br />

price, in this case the consumer price index. This profit equation is associated with input<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>/output supply functions of the following form:<br />

i<br />

k<br />

k<br />

Page 213


Appendix A: Supply response analysis<br />

q<br />

i<br />

= a<br />

i<br />

+<br />

∑<br />

j<br />

b<br />

ij<br />

p<br />

*<br />

j<br />

+<br />

∑<br />

k<br />

c<br />

ik<br />

z<br />

k<br />

The estimated coefficient, b ij , can be used to calculate the elasticity of supply (if q i is an output) <strong>and</strong><br />

the elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong> (if q i is an input).<br />

2 Data<br />

We simultaneously estimate four output supply functions <strong>and</strong> one input dem<strong>and</strong> function.<br />

The four crops are rice, maize, cassava, <strong>and</strong> sweet potatoes <strong>and</strong> the input is fertilizer. The sample<br />

includes 3762 farm households in the 1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey.<br />

Profits (π) were calculated as the value of production of rice, maize, cassava, <strong>and</strong> sweet<br />

potatoes, minus the cost of variable inputs including fertilizer, pesticides, labor, animal <strong>and</strong> equipment<br />

rental, <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> use fees. The crop production data <strong>and</strong> fertilizer use data (q i ) come from Section 9 of<br />

the questionnaire. The prices (p i ) were obtained from the community price survey. In the case of<br />

fertilizer, we used the price of Indonesian urea because this was the most common type of fertilizer<br />

used, according to the 1998 VLSS data. The fertilizer use data refer to fertilizer applied to one of the<br />

four crops. It was not possible to include pesticides because the VLSS recorded values but no<br />

quantities of pesticide use. Nor was it possible to include labor or machinery, partly because of the<br />

absence of price data in the community price survey <strong>and</strong> because the inputs were not disaggregated by<br />

crop.<br />

The vector of household characteristics (z k ) includes variables representing the productive<br />

capacity of the household, including the size of the household, the proportion of members under 10<br />

years of age, the proportion of members over 60, a binary variable for female-headed households, the<br />

age of the head of household, the number of years of education of the head of household, the amount<br />

of annual l<strong>and</strong> owned by the household, <strong>and</strong> the amount of perennial l<strong>and</strong> owned by the household.<br />

In implementing the seemingly urelated regression, we impose cross-equation restrictions,<br />

each linking a b ij coefficient in the profit equation with a b ij coefficient in one of the five output<br />

supply/input dem<strong>and</strong> equations 1 .<br />

3 Results<br />

According to economic theory (<strong>and</strong> common sense), the elasticity of supply should be<br />

positive. This means that the own-price coefficients for each output supply equation should be<br />

positive as well. The own-price coefficient in the fertilizer dem<strong>and</strong> equations would ordinarily be<br />

1<br />

We did not impose restrictions to ensure that the c ik coefficients in the profit equations were equal to<br />

those in the output supply/input dem<strong>and</strong> equations because these cofficients are not part of the calculation of<br />

price elasticities.<br />

Page 214


Appendix A: Supply response analysis<br />

negative, but input dem<strong>and</strong> is expressed as a negative number, so we expect the fertilizer own-price<br />

coefficient to be positive as well.<br />

The results, however, are not very satisfactory (see Table A1 through Table A7). The ownprice<br />

coefficient in the rice equation is negative, although not significantly different than zero. The<br />

own-price coefficients for maize, cassava, <strong>and</strong> sweet potatoes are negative <strong>and</strong> statistically significant.<br />

The own-price coefficient for fertilizer is negative, though not statistically significant. Thus, none of<br />

the five commodities yields a plausible <strong>and</strong> statistically significant supply elasticity.<br />

Various alternatives models were tried, including the following:<br />

• running the commodity equations without the profit equation, imposing cross-equation<br />

restrictions on the commodity equations.<br />

• running the model with just rice or with rice <strong>and</strong> just one or two crops<br />

• running the model with profits defined for each commodity rather than the total fourcommodity<br />

profit<br />

• running the model with fertilizer use disaggregated by crop<br />

None of these alternative versions of the model yielded satisfactory results. We suspect that<br />

the problem lies in the price data. The community price survey was carried out once during the year<br />

for each village, but the timing of the interview varied across the twelve months from November 1997<br />

to November 1998. Thus, these prices are probably not reflective of market prices facing farmers at<br />

the time of the harvest. At the same time, using unit values from sales transactions is not really a<br />

solution because it introduces endogeneity problems.<br />

Table A1. Summary of SUR model of output supply <strong>and</strong> input dem<strong>and</strong><br />

Equation Obs Parameters RMSE "R-sq" chi2 Prob<br />

profit 3762 65 2967.132 0.4572 3197.876 0.0000<br />

rice supply 3762 13 3183.321 0.4493 3069.662 0.0000<br />

maiz supply 3762 13 271.0633 0.0128 60.63578 0.0000<br />

cass supply 3762 13 1229.29 0.0194 92.70258 0.0000<br />

swpt supply 3762 13 49.67344 0.0121 64.52916 0.0000<br />

fert dem<strong>and</strong> 3762 13 388.7923 0.3534 2056.095 0.0000<br />

Page 215


Appendix A: Supply response analysis<br />

Table A2. Determinants of rice supply<br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard z Prob z<br />

error<br />

prpaddy | -.0001286 .0003784 -0.34 0.734<br />

prmaize | .0003591 .0002554 1.41 0.160<br />

prcass | .0000932 .0003846 0.24 0.809<br />

prswpt | .0003657 .0002807 1.30 0.193<br />

prurea | .0007635 .0004818 1.58 0.113<br />

hhsize | 55.81004 34.29885 1.63 0.104<br />

pchild | -8.486272 3.132246 -2.71 0.007<br />

pelder | -6.578529 2.96655 -2.22 0.027<br />

femhead | -638.9011 138.1878 -4.62 0.000<br />

age | 6.029777 5.750292 1.05 0.294<br />

educyr98 | -24.60513 14.42192 -1.71 0.088<br />

l<strong>and</strong>a | .4112849 .00798 51.54 0.000<br />

l<strong>and</strong>p | -.031664 .00932 -3.40 0.001<br />

_cons | 794.2528 361.1764 2.20 0.028<br />

Table A3. Determinants of maize supply<br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard z Prob z<br />

error<br />

prpaddy | .0003591 .0002554 1.41 0.160<br />

prmaize | -.000155 .0000466 -3.33 0.001<br />

prcass | .0004874 .0002291 2.13 0.033<br />

prswpt | -.0002284 .0001863 -1.23 0.220<br />

prurea | -.000241 .0003254 -0.74 0.459<br />

hhsize | 8.21861 2.928026 2.81 0.005<br />

pchild | .7651039 .2674482 2.86 0.004<br />

pelder | -.1388179 .253269 -0.55 0.584<br />

femhead | -2.598413 11.79571 -0.22 0.826<br />

age | 1.216743 .4909874 2.48 0.013<br />

educyr98 | 4.10231 1.231282 3.33 0.001<br />

l<strong>and</strong>a | -.000431 .0006802 -0.63 0.526<br />

l<strong>and</strong>p | -.0018548 .0007943 -2.34 0.020<br />

_cons | -60.10294 30.84316 -1.95 0.051<br />

Table A4. Determinants of cassava supply<br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard z Prob z<br />

error<br />

prpaddy | .0000932 .0003846 0.24 0.809<br />

prmaize | .0004874 .0002291 2.13 0.033<br />

prcass | -.0009673 .000235 -4.12 0.000<br />

prswpt | -.0002143 .0001754 -1.22 0.222<br />

prurea | -.000324 .0003455 -0.94 0.348<br />

hhsize | 26.4883 13.28035 1.99 0.046<br />

pchild | 2.264548 1.213035 1.87 0.062<br />

pelder | -.2868063 1.148726 -0.25 0.803<br />

femhead | -71.26664 53.50071 -1.33 0.183<br />

age | .5638511 2.226918 0.25 0.800<br />

educyr98 | -7.254478 5.584524 -1.30 0.194<br />

l<strong>and</strong>a | .0177875 .0030853 5.77 0.000<br />

l<strong>and</strong>p | .0052923 .0036028 1.47 0.142<br />

_cons | 26.80455 139.8589 0.19 0.848<br />

Page 216


Appendix A: Supply response analysis<br />

Table A5. Determinants sweet potato supply<br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard z Prob z<br />

error<br />

prpaddy | .0003657 .0002807 1.30 0.193<br />

prmaize | -.0002284 .0001863 -1.23 0.220<br />

prcass | -.0002143 .0001754 -1.22 0.222<br />

prswpt | -.0002888 .000086 -3.36 0.001<br />

prurea | -.0004492 .0003621 -1.24 0.215<br />

hhsize | .5365293 .5366869 1.00 0.317<br />

pchild | -.0817034 .0490224 -1.67 0.096<br />

pelder | -.0687734 .046422 -1.48 0.138<br />

femhead | 2.512869 2.162077 1.16 0.245<br />

age | -.0386935 .0899949 -0.43 0.667<br />

educyr98 | 1.025735 .2256978 4.54 0.000<br />

l<strong>and</strong>a | -.0002917 .0001247 -2.34 0.019<br />

l<strong>and</strong>p | -.0002653 .0001456 -1.82 0.068<br />

_cons | 7.26812 5.715504 1.27 0.203<br />

Table A6. Determinants of fertilizer dem<strong>and</strong><br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard z Prob z<br />

error<br />

prpaddy | .0007635 .0004818 1.58 0.113<br />

prmaize | -.000241 .0003254 -0.74 0.459<br />

prcass | -.000324 .0003455 -0.94 0.348<br />

prswpt | -.0004492 .0003621 -1.24 0.215<br />

prurea | -.0001196 .0002065 -0.58 0.562<br />

hhsize | .0712123 4.195949 0.02 0.986<br />

pchild | .4691922 .3832314 1.22 0.221<br />

pelder | .9433903 .3629296 2.60 0.009<br />

femhead | 79.84496 16.90407 4.72 0.000<br />

age | -1.923911 .703546 -2.73 0.006<br />

educyr98 | 1.040928 1.76437 0.59 0.555<br />

l<strong>and</strong>a | -.0412863 .0009753 -42.33 0.000<br />

l<strong>and</strong>p | .0023936 .001139 2.10 0.036<br />

_cons | -69.61031 44.20338 -1.57 0.115<br />

Note: The dependent variable (fertilizer dem<strong>and</strong>) is expressed as a<br />

negative number.<br />

Page 217


Appendix A: Supply response analysis<br />

Table A7. Determinants of profit from rice, maize, cassava,<br />

<strong>and</strong> sweet potato<br />

Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard z Prob z<br />

error<br />

Profit<br />

prpaddy | -3.478721 1.556045 -2.24 0.025<br />

prmaize | .5399842 .8299777 0.65 0.515<br />

prcass | -.1718317 1.312537 -0.13 0.896<br />

prswpt | 1.892289 .9831151 1.92 0.054<br />

prurea | .8782499 1.590409 0.55 0.581<br />

prxpr | -.0001286 .0003784 -0.34 0.734<br />

prxpm | .0003591 .0002554 1.41 0.160<br />

prxpc | .0000932 .0003846 0.24 0.809<br />

prxps | .0003657 .0002807 1.30 0.193<br />

prxpf | .0007635 .0004818 1.58 0.113<br />

pmxpm | -.000155 .0000466 -3.33 0.001<br />

pmxpc | .0004874 .0002291 2.13 0.033<br />

pmxps | -.0002284 .0001863 -1.23 0.220<br />

pmxpf | -.000241 .0003254 -0.74 0.459<br />

pcxpc | -.0009673 .000235 -4.12 0.000<br />

pcxps | -.0002143 .0001754 -1.22 0.222<br />

pcxpf | -.000324 .0003455 -0.94 0.348<br />

psxps | -.0002888 .000086 -3.36 0.001<br />

psxpf | -.0004492 .0003621 -1.24 0.215<br />

pfxpf | -.0001196 .0002065 -0.58 0.562<br />

prxz1 | .0001025 .0632808 0.00 0.999<br />

prxz2 | .0056671 .0056439 1.00 0.315<br />

prxz3 | .0066042 .0058189 1.13 0.256<br />

prxz4 | .316913 .2620689 1.21 0.227<br />

prxz5 | .0023498 .0104391 0.23 0.822<br />

prxz6 | .0254184 .028058 0.91 0.365<br />

prxz7 | .0000229 .0000144 1.59 0.111<br />

prxz8 | -.00006 .0000233 -2.57 0.010<br />

prxz9 | .0001836 .0000226 8.11 0.000<br />

pmxz1 | .0103545 .0361182 0.29 0.774<br />

pmxz2 | -.0039831 .0035212 -1.13 0.258<br />

pmxz3 | -.0020309 .0035023 -0.58 0.562<br />

pmxz4 | -.132591 .1539406 -0.86 0.389<br />

pmxz5 | -.001326 .0057124 -0.23 0.816<br />

pmxz6 | -.0012362 .0166256 -0.07 0.941<br />

pmxz7 | .0000627 .0000137 4.59 0.000<br />

pmxz8 | .0000535 .0000185 2.89 0.004<br />

pmxz9 | -.0000671 .0000148 -4.53 0.000<br />

pcxz1 | -.1017903 .0630975 -1.61 0.107<br />

pcxz2 | .0096077 .0057438 1.67 0.094<br />

pcxz3 | -.0090532 .0059012 -1.53 0.125<br />

pcxz4 | -.0419137 .2503482 -0.17 0.867<br />

pcxz5 | .0261726 .0099532 2.63 0.009<br />

pcxz6 | .0726142 .0275573 2.64 0.008<br />

pcxz7 | .0001112 .0000184 6.03 0.000<br />

pcxz8 | .0000241 .0000215 1.12 0.261<br />

pcxz9 | .0000493 .0000234 2.11 0.035<br />

psxz1 | -.0229199 .042244 -0.54 0.587<br />

psxz2 | -.0005819 .0038527 -0.15 0.880<br />

psxz3 | -.006131 .0037511 -1.63 0.102<br />

psxz4 | -.1203581 .1634973 -0.74 0.462<br />

psxz5 | .0064645 .0074442 0.87 0.385<br />

psxz6 | -.0188622 .0187995 -1.00 0.316<br />

psxz7 | .0000238 .0000155 1.53 0.125<br />

psxz8 | -.0000144 .0000182 -0.79 0.429<br />

psxz9 | -.0000492 .0000195 -2.52 0.012<br />

pfxz1 | .1241745 .0618113 2.01 0.045<br />

pfxz2 | -.0097107 .0054245 -1.79 0.073<br />

pfxz3 | -.0016171 .0057485 -0.28 0.778<br />

pfxz4 | -.4183139 .2588426 -1.62 0.106<br />

pfxz5 | -.0131855 .0096773 -1.36 0.173<br />

pfxz6 | -.0396767 .0267975 -1.48 0.139<br />

pfxz7 | -.0000219 .0000171 -1.28 0.201<br />

pfxz8 | -.0000254 .0000186 -1.37 0.172<br />

pfxz9 | -.0000728 .0000233 -3.13 0.002<br />

_cons | 2973.705 2221.023 1.34 0.181<br />

Page 218


Page 219


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Householdss<br />

Appendix B:<br />

Interview Guidelines for Farm Households<br />

Page 220


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Households<br />

Page 221


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Householdss<br />

Project:<br />

<strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> Reduction<br />

in the North Mountain Region<br />

Component:<br />

Qualitative Social Assessment<br />

Funding:<br />

JBIC - Japanese Government<br />

Implementation:<br />

International Food Policy Research Institute<br />

Farmer Interview Guidelines<br />

CONFIDENTIAL<br />

The results of these interviews are for research purposes only <strong>and</strong> are not to be revealed to or shared<br />

with any individual or organization not involved in the project during the project or after the<br />

completion of the project.<br />

Province __________________________________________<br />

District<br />

__________________________________________<br />

Commune __________________________________________<br />

Village<br />

__________________________________________<br />

Respondent __________________________________________<br />

Gender M____ F_______<br />

Date of interview Day _____ Month ________ 2002<br />

Interviewer initials ___________________<br />

1 Yen Bai 1 Tram Tau-Xa Ho ______ ________ __ __<br />

2 Tran Yen-Luong Thinh Prov. District hhold<br />

2 Ha Giang 1 Don Van- Van Chai<br />

2 Vi Xuyen- Viet Lam<br />

3 Lan Son 1 Dinh Lap-Cuong Loi<br />

2 Van Quan-Trang Phat<br />

4 Bac Giang 1 Luc Ngan-Bien Son<br />

2 Luc Nam-Nghia Phuong<br />

5 Thai Nguyen 1 Phu Luong-Phan Me<br />

2 Vo Nhai-Dan Tien<br />

6 Bac Kan 1 Ngan Son-Thuong Quan<br />

2 Choi Moi-Nong Ha<br />

7 Son La 1 Yen Chau-Phieng Khoai<br />

2 Thuan Chau-Muong Khieng<br />

8 Lai Chau 1 Muang Lay-Cha To<br />

2 Dien Bien Dong-Keo Lom<br />

Page 222


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Households<br />

Good morning/afternoon. My name is ________. I am working for a project to study the changes in<br />

the ways rural families earn money. We are interested in how income sources have changed, whether<br />

it has raised the st<strong>and</strong>ard of living of Vietnamese families, <strong>and</strong> how the government can make it easier<br />

for farmers to shift into more profitable crops <strong>and</strong> activities.<br />

As part of this study, we would like to ask you some questions about your experiences <strong>and</strong> those of<br />

your neighbors. Please try to answer as accurately as possible; your responses will not be shown to<br />

anyone. Our goal is to help the government make well-informed decisions to help all farmers in the<br />

North Mountain region, but your individual responses will not affect in any way your access to any<br />

programs, assistance, or credit. Thank you for your cooperation.<br />

A. Living conditions<br />

Please tell us a bit about yourself <strong>and</strong> your family’s living conditions.<br />

1. How old is the head of household _______years<br />

2. How many years of education does the head have _______years<br />

3. What is the ethnicity of the head ___________<br />

4. Can the head speak Vietnamese 1. Yes 2. A little 3. No ___________<br />

5. Can the head read <strong>and</strong> write Vietnamese 1. Yes 2. A little 3. No ___________<br />

6. How many people live in your household on a regular basis _____people<br />

7. How many of these are less than 10 years old _____children<br />

8. How many of these are more than 60 years old _____older people<br />

Please tell us about the l<strong>and</strong> that you use to grow crops, including both your own l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

l<strong>and</strong> you rent from others.<br />

Type of l<strong>and</strong><br />

Own with title<br />

Own without title<br />

Borrow at no charge<br />

Rent from authorities<br />

Rent from individual<br />

Other l<strong>and</strong><br />

. What<br />

is the<br />

area of<br />

lowl<strong>and</strong><br />

agricult<br />

ural<br />

l<strong>and</strong><br />

you ….<br />

(ha)<br />

0. What<br />

is the<br />

area of<br />

upl<strong>and</strong><br />

l<strong>and</strong><br />

you<br />

ha))<br />

11. Of this<br />

l<strong>and</strong>, how much is<br />

irrigated (hectares)<br />

12. How<br />

much rent do you pay<br />

for this l<strong>and</strong><br />

(VND per<br />

year or per crop or %<br />

of crop)<br />

(If area is not known, ask the weight/volume of rice seed needed to plant this field <strong>and</strong> record all local<br />

measures using respondents measure <strong>and</strong> indicate the proper conversion to kgs.)<br />

Page 223


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Householdss<br />

(It is not necessary to ask the housing question if the answer is known from direct<br />

observation)<br />

13.What type of walls does your house have ______<br />

1. Concrete<br />

2. Fired brick/stone<br />

3. Unfired brick<br />

4. Earth<br />

5. Wood/bamboo<br />

6. Other<br />

14. What type of roof does your house have ______<br />

1. Concrete<br />

2. Tile<br />

3. Metal<br />

4. Wood/bamboo<br />

5. Straw/thatch/grass<br />

6. Other<br />

15.What type of floor does your house have<br />

1. Marble/tile<br />

2. Concrete/brick<br />

3. Wood/bamboo<br />

4. Earth<br />

5. Other<br />

______<br />

16. How long has your household had electricity 0. doesn’t have yet ___no. of years<br />

______<br />

17. Does anyone in your household own a working radio 1. Yes 2. No ______<br />

18. Does anyone in your household own a working television 1. Yes 2. No ______<br />

19. Does anyone in your household own a bicycle 1. Yes 2. No ______<br />

20. Does anyone in your household own a motorbike, car, or truck 1. Yes 2. No ______<br />

21. How would you describe your household’s st<strong>and</strong>ard of living compared to others in your<br />

village<br />

1. Better than most<br />

2. About average ______<br />

3. Worse than most<br />

22. How would you describe your household’s st<strong>and</strong>ard of living now compared to in 1994<br />

1. Better than before<br />

2. About the same ______<br />

3. Worse than before<br />

Page 224


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Households<br />

1. More/less l<strong>and</strong> now than before to grow crops<br />

2. Number of harvests per year has changed<br />

3. Change in yields of crops<br />

4. Grows new crops that are more/less profitable<br />

5. Earns more/less income from livestock<br />

6. Earns more/less income from fisheries<br />

7. Earns more/less income from forestry<br />

8. Earns more/less income from wages<br />

9. Earns more/less income from non-farm<br />

business activities<br />

10. Other reason (describe):__________________<br />

_______________________________________<br />

23 Which factor<br />

was most<br />

important in<br />

changing the<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard of<br />

living of your<br />

household over<br />

the last 8 years<br />

(since 1994)<br />

24. Among<br />

households in your<br />

village that are<br />

better off now than 8<br />

years ago (1994),<br />

what is the most<br />

important way they<br />

increased their<br />

incomes<br />

25. Among<br />

households in<br />

your village that<br />

are worse off now<br />

than 8 years ago<br />

(1994), what is the<br />

most important<br />

reason their<br />

incomes fell<br />

B. Sources of household income<br />

1. Concerning rice <strong>and</strong> other food crops, last year you produced enough<br />

food to feed your household for how many months<br />

2. Has your family experienced hunger recently<br />

If yes, for how many months in the year<br />

_____months<br />

___________months<br />

We would like to ask some questions about changes in the sources of income of your household<br />

Page 225


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Householdss<br />

Rice<br />

Maize<br />

Sweet potato<br />

Potato<br />

Cassava<br />

Beans<br />

Other legumes<br />

Vegetables<br />

Litchi<br />

Longan<br />

Other fruit<br />

Tea<br />

Sugarcane<br />

Pepper<br />

Other ind. crops<br />

Opium<br />

Beef cattle<br />

Dairy cattle<br />

Buffalo<br />

Pigs<br />

Poultry<br />

Other animals<br />

Fisheries,domestic<br />

Fishing, wild<br />

Firewood<br />

Other wood<br />

Medicinal plants<br />

Wildlife<br />

Other forest prod.<br />

Mining<br />

Ag trading<br />

Other trading<br />

Ag processing<br />

Other business<br />

Ag wages<br />

Non-ag wages<br />

Remittances<br />

Family aid<br />

Government aid<br />

3. What have<br />

been the sources<br />

of income for<br />

the members of<br />

your household<br />

over the past 12<br />

months (mark<br />

1,2,3,X,X…)<br />

4. Which of<br />

these are new<br />

sources of<br />

income in that<br />

you did not have<br />

them in 1994<br />

(mark with X)<br />

5. Which of<br />

these income<br />

sources have<br />

you had since<br />

1994 but do not<br />

have now<br />

(mark with X)<br />

6. Of the activities<br />

you have had since<br />

1994, which ones<br />

have become more<br />

important over<br />

time relative to<br />

others<br />

(mark with X)<br />

7. Of the<br />

activities you<br />

have had since<br />

1994, which ones<br />

have become less<br />

important over<br />

time relative to<br />

others (mark<br />

with X)<br />

Page 226


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Households<br />

Now, we would like to ask about the income sources that are most common among your friends <strong>and</strong><br />

neighbors<br />

Rice<br />

Maize<br />

Sweet potato<br />

Potato<br />

Cassava<br />

Beans<br />

Other legumes<br />

Vegetables<br />

Litchi<br />

Longan<br />

Other fruit<br />

Tea<br />

Sugarcane<br />

Pepper<br />

Other ind. crops<br />

Opium<br />

Beef cattle<br />

Dairly cattle<br />

Buffalo<br />

Pigs<br />

Poultry<br />

Other animals<br />

Fisheries,domestic<br />

Fishing, wild<br />

Firewood<br />

Other wood<br />

Medicinal plants<br />

Wildlife<br />

Other forest products<br />

Mining<br />

Ag trading<br />

Other trading<br />

Ag processing<br />

Other business<br />

Ag wages<br />

Non-ag wages<br />

Remittances<br />

Family aid<br />

Government aid<br />

8. What are the most<br />

common sources of<br />

income among<br />

people in your<br />

village<br />

(mark 1,2,3,X,X,…)<br />

9. Which income<br />

sources have become<br />

more important in<br />

your village since<br />

1994<br />

(mark with X)<br />

10. Which income<br />

sources have become<br />

less important in<br />

your village since<br />

1994<br />

(mark with X)<br />

Page 227


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Householdss<br />

C. Constraints on diversification<br />

1. Do you think that if you grew different crops, 1. Yes 2. No ______<br />

you could earn more money<br />

2. (If yes) Which crops do you think would earn more _______ _______ _______<br />

3. (If yes) Why don’t you grow these crops<br />

4. Have you grown any new crops since 1994 that have turned out to be profitable<br />

enough to continue growing them 1. Yes 2. No<br />

_______<br />

5. (If yes) Which crop turned out to be profitable (or the most profitable) _______<br />

6. (If yes) What was the main factor that convinced you to try growing this crop _______<br />

1. Encouragement or assistance from extension agent<br />

2. Encouragement or assistance from local authorities<br />

3. Encouragement or assistance from a state enterprise<br />

4. Encouragement or assistance from a private trader<br />

5. Other ___________________________<br />

7. What type of incentives did they offer to grow this new crop<br />

a. Showed how to grow the crop 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

b. Provided the inputs for sale 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

c. Provided inputs on credit or free 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

d. Assured that a market exists for the output 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

e. Guaranteed to purchase the output 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

f. Other _________________________<br />

8. Have you grown any new crops since 1994 that have turned out not to be profitable<br />

enough to continue growing them 1. Yes 2. No<br />

_______<br />

9. (If yes) Which crops turned out not to be profitable (or the least profitable) _______<br />

10. (If yes) What was the main factor that convinced you to try growing this crop _______<br />

1. Encouragement or assistance from extension agent<br />

2. Encouragement or assistance from local authorities<br />

3. Encouragement or assistance from a state enterprise<br />

4. Encouragement or assistance from a private trader<br />

5. Other ___________________________<br />

11. What type of incentives did they offer to grow this new crop<br />

a. Showed how to grow the crop 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

b. Provided the inputs for sale 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

c. Provided inputs on credit or free 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

d. Assured that a market exists for the output 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

e. Guaranteed to purchase the output 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

f. Other _________________________<br />

12. Do you think that if you got involved in income-generating activities other than growing crops,<br />

you could earn more money 1. Yes 2. No<br />

_______<br />

13. (If yes) Which activities would be more profitable_______ _______ _______<br />

Page 228


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Households<br />

14. (If yes) Why don’t you get involved in these activities<br />

15. What do you think are the main reasons that some people are poor in your village<br />

16. Do you think that growing different crops could increase their income<br />

1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

17. (If yes) Why don’t they try these new crops then<br />

18. Do you think that fisheries or livestock would increase their income<br />

1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

19. (If yes) Why don’t they try these activities<br />

20. Do you think that small businesses or wage income would increase their income<br />

1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

21. (If yes) Why don’t they try these activities<br />

22. Do you think it is more difficult for female farmers to try new crops or new activities<br />

1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

23. (If yes) Why is it more difficult for female farmers to try new crops or new activities<br />

24. Do you think it is more difficult for farmers from some ethnic groups to try<br />

new crops or activities 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

25. (If yes) For which ethnic groups is it more difficult_______ _______ _______<br />

26. (If yes) Why is it more difficult for these ethnic groups to try new crops or activities<br />

Page 229


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Householdss<br />

D. Role of traders <strong>and</strong> processors<br />

1 Does your household sell any crops 1. Yes 2. No ______<br />

(If yes) Please answer the following questions:<br />

2. What<br />

are the<br />

three most<br />

important<br />

crops that<br />

your<br />

household<br />

sells<br />

3. Who do you<br />

usually sell your<br />

[crop] to<br />

1. Private trader<br />

2. State trading<br />

enterprise<br />

2. Private processor<br />

3. State processor<br />

4. Cooperative<br />

5. Consumers<br />

6. Others<br />

4. Does this buyer<br />

provide any assistance<br />

in growing the crop<br />

1. No assistance<br />

2. Info on how to grow<br />

3. Sells inputs<br />

4. Offers inputs on<br />

credit<br />

5. Pre-harvest price<br />

guarantee<br />

6. Combination of<br />

above<br />

5. How many<br />

buyers of this crop<br />

are there for you to<br />

choose from<br />

(consider only<br />

those that buy in<br />

same location as<br />

actual buyer)<br />

1. More than 10<br />

2. 5-10<br />

3. 2-5<br />

4. Only one<br />

5. Don’t know<br />

.<br />

6. Why do you sell<br />

to this buyer <strong>and</strong> not<br />

another one<br />

1. Only one<br />

available<br />

2. Offers assistance<br />

3. Best price<br />

4. Trust/personal<br />

relation<br />

5. Owe money to this<br />

buyer<br />

6. Other<br />

7. If yes, how much debt do you owe to processors <strong>and</strong> traders___________________<br />

8. If yes, how much debt do you owe to all other sources (banks, relatives,<br />

friends)________<br />

9. Regarding the most important buyer (in value terms) of your crops, how long have you been selling<br />

to him/her<br />

1. Have sold to him/her for many years ______<br />

2. Have sold to him/her for several years<br />

3. Have sold to him/her for just a few years<br />

4. This was the first year I sold to him/her<br />

10. Regarding this same buyer, how much do you trust him/her to give you a fair price<br />

1. I trust him/her to give me a fair price<br />

2. I trust him/her more or less, but I verify that the price is fair _______<br />

3. I don’t trust him/her very much.<br />

4. I think that he/she gives me an unfair price every time<br />

11. Has a private trader or processor ever given you any encouragement or assistance to try a new<br />

crop 1. Yes 2. No ______<br />

12. (If yes) Which crops were you encouraged to try ______ ______ ______<br />

13. (If yes) What type of encouragement or assistance did they give you to try new crops<br />

a. Showed how to grow the crop 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

b. Provided the inputs for sale 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

c. Provided inputs on credit or free 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

d. Assured that a market exists for the output 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

e. Guarenteed to purchase the output 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

f. Other _________________________<br />

14. (If yes) Was it useful or not 1. Yes 2. No ________<br />

15. (If not useful) Why wasn’t this assistance useful<br />

Page 230


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Households<br />

16. Are there any traders that buy your crops <strong>and</strong> live in this commune If yes, please list:<br />

Name Location Ethnicity<br />

E. Role of government<br />

1. How many times did you attend an agricultural extension meeting<br />

during the past 12 months<br />

2 (If no) In the past year, have you received extension information indirectly ,<br />

for example from friend, radio program, or brochure 1. Yes 2. No<br />

______times<br />

_______<br />

3 Has the extension agent or other government officials given you any encouragement or assistance<br />

to try new crops 1. Yes 2. No ______<br />

4 (If yes) Which crops were you encouraged to try ______ ______ ______<br />

5 (If yes) What type of encouragement or assistance did they give you to try new crops<br />

a. Showed how to grow the crop 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

b. Provided the inputs for sale 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

c. Provided inputs on credit or free 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

d. Assured that a market exists for the output 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

e. Guarenteed to purchase the output 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

f. Other _________________________<br />

6 (If yes) Was it useful or not 1. Yes 2. No ________<br />

7 (If useful) How much did this new crop improve your households’ st<strong>and</strong>ard of living<br />

8 (If not useful) Why wasn’t this assistance useful<br />

9 Has the extension agent or other government officials given you any encouragement or<br />

assistance to try new income generating activities other than crops<br />

1. Yes 2. No ________<br />

10 (If yes) Which activities were you encouraged to try ______ ______ ______<br />

11 (If yes) What type of encouragement or assistance did they give you to try these activities<br />

a. Showed how to do it 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

b. Provided credit 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

c. Recommended to bank for credit 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

d. Provided information on market 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

e. Guarenteed to purchase the output 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

f. Other _________________________<br />

12 (If yes) Was it useful or not 1. Yes 2. No _______<br />

13 (If useful) How much did this new crop improve your households’ st<strong>and</strong>ard of living<br />

Page 231


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Householdss<br />

14 (If not useful) Why wasn’t this assistance useful<br />

15 What do you think are the three most useful types of government assistance to reduce poverty in<br />

this province [do not read list unless enumerator has trouble answering]<br />

1. Better education <strong>and</strong> health care _______<br />

2. Build better road to village<br />

3. Build or exp<strong>and</strong> irrigation system in village _______<br />

4. Exp<strong>and</strong> or improve electrification<br />

5. Improve access to clean water _______<br />

6. Better access to credit<br />

7. Promote new crops <strong>and</strong> their marketing<br />

8. Better support for existing annual <strong>and</strong> tree crops <strong>and</strong> livestock<br />

9. Promote h<strong>and</strong>icraft or other jobs in or near village<br />

10. Other: ________________________________<br />

16 What do you think is the most useful type of government assistance to help farmers grow<br />

different, more profitable crops<br />

17 What do you think is the most useful type of government assistance to help farmers try new noncrop<br />

economic activities<br />

Thank you for your time <strong>and</strong> assistance.<br />

Page 232


Appendix B: Interview Guidelines for Farm Households<br />

Page 233


Page 234


Appendix C: Interview Guidelines for Provincial Authorities<br />

Appendix C:<br />

Interview Guidelines for Provincial Authorities<br />

Page 235


Appendix C: Interview Guidelines for Provincial Authorities<br />

Page 236


Appendix C: Interview Guidelines for Provincial Authorities<br />

Project:<br />

<strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Poverty</strong> Reduction<br />

in the North Mountain Region<br />

Component:<br />

Qualitative Social Assessment<br />

Funding:<br />

JBIC – Japanese Government<br />

Implementation:<br />

International Food Policy Research Institute<br />

Guidelines for Interviews with Provincial Authorities<br />

CONFIDENTIAL INFORMATION<br />

The results of these interviews are for research purposes only <strong>and</strong> are not to be revealed to or shared<br />

with any individual or organization not involved in the project during the project or after the<br />

completion of the project..<br />

Page 237


Appendix C: Interview Guidelines for Provincial Authorities<br />

Notes for interviewer<br />

The responses to this interview will be recorded in your notebooks. These guidelines are to make sure<br />

that all the notebooks are organized in a similar way, making it easier for yourself <strong>and</strong> others to use<br />

the information.<br />

Before beginning the interview, record the following information in your notebook at the top of a new<br />

page. Draw a box around the information so it is easy to see where a new interview begins.<br />

Province<br />

Name of respondent<br />

Title of respondent<br />

Date of interview<br />

In order to make it easy for others to read <strong>and</strong> underst<strong>and</strong> your notes, please organize your notes as<br />

follows:<br />

1) Start the answers to each question on a new line<br />

2) Put the question number on the left side <strong>and</strong> circle it<br />

3) Leave a space between answers<br />

You are encouraged to ask additional questions to follow up on interesting topics, but please be sure<br />

the following topics are covered.<br />

Interview<br />

Good morning/afternoon. My name is ________. I am working for a project to study the changes in<br />

the ways rural families earn income. In particular, we are interested in how they shift from growing<br />

mainly rice <strong>and</strong> other food crops to growing higher-value agricultural commodities <strong>and</strong> how they shift<br />

from agriculture to non-farm activities. We are also interested in whether these changes raise<br />

household incomes <strong>and</strong>, if so, how the government can make it easier for farmers to makes these<br />

changes. As part of this study, we would like to ask you about the experiences of this province.<br />

1. Have there been changes in the types of crops grown by farmers in this province since 1994<br />

2. (If yes) What crops have increased in terms of their share of the total planted area<br />

3. (If yes) What crops have decreased in terms of their share of the total planted area<br />

4. What motivated farmers to increased the area planted with [crop 1 & 2]<br />

5. Did the government promote the expansion of [crop 1 & 2] or did it happen spontaneously<br />

6. (If government promoted) What role did the central government play in promoting the<br />

production of [crop 1 & 2]<br />

7. (If government promoted) What role did the provincial government play in promoting the<br />

production of [crop 1 & 2]<br />

8. In general, does the provincial government provide low-cost seed <strong>and</strong> fertilizer to farmers to<br />

promote specific crops<br />

9. (If yes) Which crops, what type of assistance, <strong>and</strong> how is it organized<br />

10. (If yes) How much is the annual budget for this type of assistance to farmers<br />

Page 238


Appendix C: Interview Guidelines for Provincial Authorities<br />

11. Does the provincial government provide any assistance in marketing to promote specific<br />

crops<br />

12. (If yes) Which crops, what type of assistance, <strong>and</strong> how is it organized<br />

13. (If yes) How much is the annual budget for this type of assistance to farmers<br />

14. How does the provincial government decide which crops to promote<br />

15. {If based on l<strong>and</strong> use plans} How are the l<strong>and</strong> use plans prepared<br />

16. How does it decide which areas are appropriate for promoting each crop<br />

17. Are there any crops that have exp<strong>and</strong>ed significantly without being promoted by the<br />

provincial government<br />

18. (If yes) Which crops <strong>and</strong> how were they promoted<br />

19. (If yes) What role did private traders play in promoting the production of this crop<br />

20. What is the policy of the provincial government regarding this “spontaneous” expansion<br />

21. Do you believe that private traders play a positive or negative role in promoting new crops<br />

Why<br />

22. What provincial state-owned enterprises are involved in providing seed, fertilizer, <strong>and</strong> other<br />

inputs in this province<br />

23. What provincial state-owned enterprises are involved in processing agricultural commodities<br />

in this province<br />

24. Are any of these scheduled to be restructured (equitized) within the next five years or will<br />

they remain provincial enterprises<br />

[Note to interviewers: write in your notebook the following information for each district using a table<br />

like the one below or a list]<br />

In order to learn more about the differences among the districts in this province, we would like to ask<br />

some questions about each of the districts in this province.<br />

District name Degree of<br />

access to<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

of living<br />

Main crops or activities that have<br />

increased since 1994<br />

Main obstacles to agricultural<br />

development<br />

markets<br />

1 Poor<br />

2 Average<br />

3 Good<br />

1 Very<br />

poor<br />

2 Poor<br />

3 Fair<br />

(write “None” if little or no<br />

change in crops <strong>and</strong> activities)<br />

1<br />

2<br />

etc..<br />

Thank you for your time.<br />

Page 239


Page 240


Appendix D: Constructing a st<strong>and</strong>ard of living index<br />

Appendix D:<br />

Constructing an index of st<strong>and</strong>ard of living for the QSAID Household Survey<br />

Page 241


Appendix D: Constructing a st<strong>and</strong>ard of living index<br />

Page 242


Appendix D: Constructing a st<strong>and</strong>ard of living index<br />

Calculating household income or expenditure directly requires a large number of questions<br />

that typically occupy tens of pages when done thoroughly. When income <strong>and</strong> expenditure are<br />

estimated based on small numbers of questions, the reliability of the results may be low. In this study,<br />

we construct an index of household st<strong>and</strong>ard of living by combining household characteristics<br />

collected in our survey with an analysis of the relationship between household characteristics <strong>and</strong> per<br />

capita expenditure in the 1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey. This method follows an approach<br />

used to generate poverty maps using household survey <strong>and</strong> census data (see Minot, 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2000<br />

<strong>and</strong> Hentschel 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2000).<br />

The first step is to select a set of household characteristics that may be correlated with<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard of living <strong>and</strong> are found in both the Qualitative Social Assessment <strong>Income</strong> <strong>Diversification</strong><br />

Household Survey <strong>and</strong> in the 1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey. The household characteristics<br />

used in this analysis are shown in Table D-1, <strong>and</strong> the descriptive statistics for these variables from the<br />

QSAID Household Survey are show in Table D-2.<br />

.<br />

Table D-1.<br />

Variable<br />

name<br />

age<br />

educ<br />

ethnic<br />

hhsize<br />

under10<br />

over60<br />

elect<br />

wall2<br />

wall3<br />

wall4<br />

wall5<br />

floor1<br />

floor2<br />

floor4<br />

floor5<br />

roof1<br />

roof2<br />

roof3<br />

roof4<br />

roof6<br />

radio<br />

TV<br />

bike<br />

vehicle<br />

Description of variable<br />

Age of head of household (years)<br />

Education of head of household (years)<br />

Head of household is ethnic minority<br />

(0 = Kinh or Hoa, 1 = other minority)<br />

Size of household (number of members)<br />

Number of children under 10 years old<br />

Number of adults over 60 years old<br />

Electification of the household (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Walls of fired brick or stone (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Walls of unfired brick (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Walls of earth (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Walls of bamboo or wood (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Floor made of marble or tile (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Floor made of concrete or brick (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Floor made of earth (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Floor made of other material (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Roof of concrete (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Roof of tile (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Roof of metal (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Roof of wood or bamboo (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Roof of other material (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Household owns a working radio (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Household owns a television (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Household owns a bicycle (0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Household owns a motorbike or other vehicle<br />

(0 = no, 1 = yes)<br />

Page 243


Appendix D: Constructing a st<strong>and</strong>ard of living index<br />

Table D-2. Descriptive statistics of household characteristics in the<br />

QSAID Household Survey<br />

Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max<br />

age 307 41.00977 10.94863 19 73<br />

educ 307 5.315961 3.227917 0 16<br />

ethnic 307 .8078176 .3946589 0 1<br />

hhsize 307 5.856678 2.492927 2 18<br />

under10 307 1.18241 1.233764 0 7<br />

over60 307 .4462541 .6998207 0 2<br />

elect 307 .6351792 .4821658 0 1<br />

wall2 307 .2052117 .4045156 0 1<br />

wall3 307 .019544 .1386529 0 1<br />

wall4 307 .218241 .4137263 0 1<br />

wall5 307 .5211726 .5003671 0 1<br />

floor1 307 .0684039 .2528499 0 1<br />

floor2 307 .218241 .4137263 0 1<br />

floor4 307 .4918567 .5007499 0 1<br />

floor5 307 .029316 .1689661 0 1<br />

roof1 307 .0618893 .2413477 0 1<br />

roof2 307 .5602606 .4971658 0 1<br />

roof3 307 .0325733 .1778068 0 1<br />

roof4 307 .0586319 .2353181 0 1<br />

roof6 307 .0260586 .1595698 0 1<br />

radio 307 .5635179 .4967588 0 1<br />

TV 307 .5114007 .5006861 0 1<br />

bike 307 .5407166 .499153 0 1<br />

vehicle 307 .4136808 .4932967 0 1<br />

Source: QSAID Household Survey.<br />

In the 1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey, there are 663 households in the rural areas of<br />

the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region. The descriptive statistics of the same household characteristics for these<br />

households are shown in Table D-3.<br />

The respondents of the QSAID Household Survey are generally pretty similar to those in the<br />

1998 VLSS. The household heads in the QSAID Household Survey are slightly younger (41 vs 44<br />

years old), somewhat less educated (5.3 years vs 7.5 years), <strong>and</strong> significantly more likely to be ethnic<br />

minorities (81 percent vs 48 percent). The household size <strong>and</strong> composition are very close to what was<br />

found in the 1998 VLSS, as is the percentage of houses with electricity. In our sample, wood <strong>and</strong><br />

bamboo walls were the most common, whereas the VLSS had more houses of fired brick <strong>and</strong> stone.<br />

In both surveys, earth floors were the most common, followed by concrete or brick, though earth<br />

floors were more common in our survey (49 percent vs 40 percent). In both surveys, tile roofs were<br />

the most common, representing 56 percent of the responses in our survey <strong>and</strong> 67 percent of the<br />

responses in the VLSS. With regard to ownership of consumer goods, the QSAID respondents were<br />

somewhat more likely to own a radio (56 percent vs. 43 percent) <strong>and</strong> a television (51 percent vs. 43<br />

percent), less likely to own a bicycle (54<br />

Page 244


Appendix D: Constructing a st<strong>and</strong>ard of living index<br />

Table D-3. Descriptive statistics of household characteristics from the rural<br />

Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region from the 1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey<br />

Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max<br />

age 663 44.0724 12.90791 20 87<br />

educ 663 7.45098 3.941444 0 18<br />

ethnic 663 .4751131 .4997573 0 1<br />

hhsize 663 5.122172 1.697298 1 12<br />

under10 663 1.152338 1.07962 0 5<br />

over60 663 .4208145 .692638 0 4<br />

elect 663 .6576169 .4748653 0 1<br />

wall2 663 .4147813 .4930562 0 1<br />

wall3 663 .0693816 .2542938 0 1<br />

wall4 663 .1674208 .373633 0 1<br />

wall5 663 .3152338 .4649597 0 1<br />

wall6 663 .0331825 .1792481 0 1<br />

floor1 663 .0422323 .2012705 0 1<br />

floor2 663 .3092006 .462513 0 1<br />

floor3 663 .1372549 .3443761 0 1<br />

floor4 663 .3966817 .4895782 0 1<br />

floor5 663 .1146305 .318816 0 1<br />

roof1 663 .0708899 .2568346 0 1<br />

roof2 663 .6651584 .4722914 0 1<br />

roof3 663 .0060332 .0774974 0 1<br />

roof4 663 .0060332 .0774974 0 1<br />

roof5 663 .2368024 .425441 0 1<br />

roof6 663 .015083 .121975 0 1<br />

radio 663 .4268477 .4949932 0 1<br />

TV 663 .4313725 .4956418 0 1<br />

bike 663 .7179487 .4503379 0 1<br />

vehicle 663 .1116139 .3151285 0 1<br />

Source: 1998 Vietnam Living St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey.<br />

percent vs 72 percent), <strong>and</strong> more likely to own a motorbike or other vehicle (41 percent vs 11<br />

percent). Some of these increases in ownership of consumer goods may represent changes in rural<br />

incomes between 1998 when the VLSS was carried out <strong>and</strong> 2002 when the QSAID Household Survey<br />

was implemented. Thus, overall, the two surveys had similar samples, the most significant difference<br />

being that our survey had a larger proportion of ethnic minority households <strong>and</strong> a larger proportion of<br />

households owning radios, televisions, <strong>and</strong> motor vehicles.<br />

The second step in the analysis is to estimate the relationship between per capita expenditure<br />

(in natural logarithm form) <strong>and</strong> the household characteristics using the 1998 Vietnam Living<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ards Survey. After some experimentation with different set of variables, the specification shown<br />

in Table D-4 was adopted. The regression analysis was carried out with adjustments for the sample<br />

design effects of the VLSS 2 . The results are shown in Table D-4. The value of R 2 indicates that the<br />

household characteristics explain about 55 percent of the variation in the dependent variable, per<br />

capita consumption expenditure.<br />

Table D-4. Estimation of per capita expenditure using the VLSS<br />

Dependent variable: Log of per capita consumption expenditure<br />

pweight: hhsizewt Number of obs = 663<br />

Strata: reg10 Number of strata = 1<br />

2 Compared to a pure r<strong>and</strong>om sample, a typical survey is stratified to improve the accuracy of estimates<br />

<strong>and</strong> clustered to reduce the costs of data collection. Stratification tends to reduce the st<strong>and</strong>ard errors of<br />

econometrically estimated coefficients, while clustering increases them, relative to a simple r<strong>and</strong>om survey. In<br />

Stata, the “svyreg” comm<strong>and</strong> takes into account these sample design effects in calculating st<strong>and</strong>ard errors.<br />

Page 245


Appendix D: Constructing a st<strong>and</strong>ard of living index<br />

PSU: commune Number of PSUs = 21<br />

Population size = 11832003<br />

F( 19, 2) = .<br />

Subpopulation no. of obs = 663 Prob > F = .<br />

Subpopulation size = 11832003 R-squared = 0.5500<br />

lnx Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t [95% Conf. Interval]<br />

age .0042999 .0014245 3.02 0.007 .0013285 .0072714<br />

educ .0105377 .0052516 2.01 0.059 -.000417 .0214924<br />

ethnic -.014118 .0616715 -0.23 0.821 -.1427625 .1145266<br />

hhsize -.0782434 .0085664 -9.13 0.000 -.0961125 -.0603742<br />

under10 -.0499272 .0187303 -2.67 0.015 -.0889978 -.0108565<br />

over60 -.0268649 .0147785 -1.82 0.084 -.0576923 .0039625<br />

elect .0350259 .0466919 0.75 0.462 -.0623717 .1324235<br />

wall2 -.0239807 .0542616 -0.44 0.663 -.1371684 .089207<br />

wall3 .017033 .076278 0.22 0.826 -.1420803 .1761462<br />

wall5 .0619671 .0546473 1.13 0.270 -.052025 .1759593<br />

wall6 .0691974 .0715245 0.97 0.345 -.08 .2183948<br />

roof1 .300134 .0545428 5.50 0.000 .1863596 .4139084<br />

roof2 .1412324 .036459 3.87 0.001 .0651802 .2172847<br />

roof3 .5579362 .209306 2.67 0.015 .1213315 .9945409<br />

roof4 .1399553 .083177 1.68 0.108 -.0335489 .3134594<br />

roof6 .1961712 .0747631 2.62 0.016 .0402181 .3521243<br />

floor1 .2407958 .0862533 2.79 0.011 .0608746 .4207171<br />

floor2 .1446203 .0539832 2.68 0.014 .0320134 .2572273<br />

floor3 .0590639 .0754611 0.78 0.443 -.0983451 .216473<br />

floor5 .1952154 .0619933 3.15 0.005 .0658997 .3245312<br />

radio .0230109 .0319163 0.72 0.479 -.0435653 .0895872<br />

TV .1801767 .0302906 5.95 0.000 .1169915 .2433618<br />

bike -.0018102 .043775 -0.04 0.967 -.0931233 .0895028<br />

vehicle .290211 .0283423 10.24 0.000 .2310899 .349332<br />

cons 7.317791 .1242968 58.87 0.000 7.058512 7.577069<br />

Age <strong>and</strong> education are statistically significant <strong>and</strong> positively correlated with per capita<br />

expenditure. Household size <strong>and</strong> number of children below 10 are significant <strong>and</strong> negatively<br />

correlated. F-tests of the joint significance of the housing characteristics indicate that the type of wall<br />

is not statistically significant, but the type of floor <strong>and</strong> the type of roof are significant. Ownership of<br />

televisions <strong>and</strong> vehicles are statistically significant <strong>and</strong> positively correlated, as expected.<br />

Electrification of the house is not statistically significant, perhaps because this is determined more by<br />

location <strong>and</strong> village characteristics than household purchasing power. Ownership of radios <strong>and</strong><br />

bicycles are also not significant; possibly, high income households are more likely to use televisions<br />

for communication <strong>and</strong> motorbikes for transport.<br />

The third step is to apply this equation to the same household characteristics in the QSAID<br />

Household Survey. This generates an estimated log per capita expenditure for each household in the<br />

sample. We use this variable to divide our sample into three groups of equal size to compare the<br />

patterns of diversification across categories. Although the categories represent terciles of estimated<br />

per capita consumption expenditure based on household characteristics, we use the terms “income<br />

tercile” <strong>and</strong> “income category” for convenience. It should be kept in mind that the “higher-income”<br />

tercile represent the top third of rural household in the Northern Upl<strong>and</strong> region, but they are still poor<br />

by international st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>and</strong> even compared to Vietnamese households in urban areas <strong>and</strong> many<br />

rural<br />

areas.<br />

Page 246


Appendix E: Details of MacroSAM Construction<br />

Page 247


Appendix E: Details of MacroSAM Construction<br />

Appendix E:<br />

Details of the MacroSAM construction<br />

Page 248


Appendix E: Details of MacroSAM construction<br />

Page 249


Appendix E: Details of MacroSAM construction<br />

Description of Individual Cells in the Macro SAM<br />

Cell (1,2) “Activities-Commodities”: Marketed production<br />

This transaction corresponds to the total value of sales (at producer prices) in the activities<br />

row. The gross output figures for each region reported in GSO (2002) has been adjusted in order<br />

balance row <strong>and</strong> column totals. By definition gross output is equal to intermediate consumption, total<br />

value added <strong>and</strong> total indirect taxes.<br />

Cell (2,1) “Commodities-Activities”: Intermediate consumption<br />

Intermediate consumption in producer prices is reported in GSO (2002) for each region. The<br />

numbers are used directly in the individual Macro SAMs.<br />

Cell (2,4) “Commodities-Households”: Private consumption<br />

Private consumption is taken directly from the balance sheet of gross domestic product as<br />

documented in GSO (2002) for each region <strong>and</strong> is used directly in the individual Macro SAMs.<br />

Cell (2,6) “Commodities-Prov. Government”: Provincial government consumption<br />

GSO (2002) documents the total provincial consumption (current expenditure plus<br />

expenditure for construction) for each province. For 11 regions this entry is derived by deducting cells<br />

(2,7), (4,7), (5,7), (8,7) <strong>and</strong> (9,7) from the total provincial consumption. In three cases (Lang Son, Phu<br />

Tho <strong>and</strong> Quang Ninh) the provincial consumption in each province enters directly in the individual<br />

Macro SAMs.<br />

Cell (2,7) “Commodities-Central Government”: Central government consumption<br />

As for private consumption, central government consumption data is obtained from the<br />

balance sheet for gross domestic product documented in GSO (2002) for each region <strong>and</strong> is used<br />

directly in the individual Macro SAMs.<br />

Cell (2,8) “Commodities-Investment/Savings”: Investment<br />

Gross capital formation, which is the sum of fixed capital formation <strong>and</strong> changes in<br />

inventories is reported by GSO (2002) for each region <strong>and</strong> is used directly in the individual Macro<br />

SAMs.<br />

Cell (2,9) “Commodities-ROW”: Exports<br />

GSO (2002) only reports net imports for each region. Using import shares of total output in<br />

the national Macro SAM documented in Tarp et. al. (2002) <strong>and</strong> applying this information to each<br />

region together with the region specific net import numbers, data on exports <strong>and</strong> imports for the 14<br />

regions becomes available. Additional adjustments of the export numbers had to done in order to<br />

secure balance of each Macro SAM.<br />

Cell (3,1) “Factors-Activities”: Value added<br />

Total value added can be calculated as the sum of compensation of employees, consumption<br />

of fixed capital, operating surplus <strong>and</strong> production taxes. The data are documented in GSO (2002). The<br />

production tax figures in GSO (2002) has been adjusted as described below.<br />

Cell (4,3) “Households-Factors”: Wages, salaries <strong>and</strong> other benefits<br />

Compensation of employees is reported by GSO (2002) for each region <strong>and</strong> is used directly in<br />

the individual Macro SAMs.<br />

Cell (4,5) “Households-Enterprises”: Distributed profits <strong>and</strong> social security<br />

Page 250


Appendix E: Details of MacroSAM construction<br />

This entry is derived by using the output share of distributed profits <strong>and</strong> social security from<br />

the national Macro SAM documented in Tarp et. al. (2002), multiplied by the region specific output<br />

number from cell (1,2).<br />

Cell (4,6) “Households-Prov. Government”: Social security<br />

This entry is documented in GSO (2002) for each region, <strong>and</strong> is used directly in the individual<br />

Macro SAMs.<br />

Cell (4,7) “Households-Central Government”: Social security<br />

This entry is derived by using the output share of social security from the national Macro<br />

SAM documented in Tarp et. al. (2002), multiplied by the region specific output number from cell<br />

(1,2). In some of the regions additional adjustments of the social security numbers had to done in<br />

order to secure balance of the regional Macro SAM.<br />

Cell (4,9) “Households-ROW”: Net foreign transfers to households<br />

This entry is derived by using the output share of net foreign transfers to households from the<br />

Macro SAM documented in Tarp et. al. (2002), multiplied by the region specific total net foreign<br />

transfer to government number from cells (6,9) <strong>and</strong> (7,9). In some of the regions additional<br />

adjustments of the net foreign transfer to households number had to done in order to secure balance of<br />

the regional Macro SAM.<br />

Cell (5,3) “Enterprises-Factors”: Gross profits<br />

Returns to capital are calculated by adding consumption of fixed capital <strong>and</strong> operating<br />

surplus. These flows are documented in GSO (2002) <strong>and</strong> is entered directly in the individual Macro<br />

SAMs.<br />

Cell (5,7) “Enterprises-State”: Enterprise subsidies<br />

This entry is derived by using the output share of enterprise subsidies from the Macro SAM<br />

documented in Tarp et. al. (2002), multiplied by the region specific gross output number from cell<br />

(1,2). In some of the regions additional adjustments of the enterprise subsidy number had to done in<br />

order to secure balance of the regional Macro SAM.<br />

Cell (5,9) “Enterprises-ROW”: Net foreign transfers to enterprises<br />

This entry is derived by using the output share of net foreign transfers to enterprises from the<br />

Macro SAM documented in Tarp et. al. (2002), multiplied by the region specific total net foreign<br />

transfer to government number from cells (6,9) <strong>and</strong> (7,9). In some of the regions additional<br />

adjustments of the net foreign transfer to enterprises number had to done in order to secure balance of<br />

the regional Macro SAM.<br />

Cell (6,1) “Prov. Government-Activities”: Value added taxes<br />

This entry is derived by using the provincial budget data provided by GSO (2002) for each<br />

region. Cell (6,1) include: Value added taxes, taxes on l<strong>and</strong> use of agricultural l<strong>and</strong>, taxes on transfer<br />

of l<strong>and</strong> use rights, fees on l<strong>and</strong> use rights, <strong>and</strong> other fees <strong>and</strong> taxes. Furthermore “other revenue” in<br />

GSO (2002) was split upon cells (6,1), (6,2), (6,3), (6,4), (6,5) <strong>and</strong> (6,9) according to the tax structure<br />

in the national Macro SAM documented in Tarp et. al. (2002).<br />

Cell (6,2) “Prov. Government-Commodities”: Trade taxes<br />

This entry is derived by using the provincial budget data provided by GSO (2002) for each<br />

region. Cell (6,2) include: Taxes on imports, taxes on exports, excise duties, <strong>and</strong> VAT on imports.<br />

Furthermore “other revenue” in GSO (2002) was split upon cells (6,1), (6,2), (6,3), (6,4), (6,5) <strong>and</strong><br />

(6,9) according to the tax structure in the national Macro SAM documented in Tarp et. al. (2002).<br />

Page 251


Appendix E: Details of MacroSAM construction<br />

Cell (6,3) “Prov. Government-Factors”: Factor taxes<br />

Cell (6,3) include “Other revenue” documented in GSO (2002), which was split upon cells<br />

(6,1), (6,2), (6,3), (6,4), (6,5) <strong>and</strong> (6,9) according to the tax structure in the national Macro SAM<br />

documented in Tarp et. al. (2002).<br />

Cell (6,4) “Prov. Government-Households”: <strong>Income</strong> taxes<br />

This entry is derived by using the provincial budget data provided by GSO (2002) for each<br />

region. Cell (6,4) include personal income taxes. Furthermore “other revenue” in GSO (2002) was<br />

split upon cells (6,1), (6,2), (6,3), (6,4), (6,5) <strong>and</strong> (6,9) according to the tax structure in the national<br />

Macro SAM documented in Tarp et. al. (2002).<br />

Cell (6,5) “Prov. Goverment-Enterprises”: Enterprise taxes<br />

This entry is derived by using the provincial budget data provided by GSO (2002) for each<br />

region. Cell (6,5) include corporate income taxes. Furthermore “other revenue” in GSO (2002) was<br />

split upon cells (6,1), (6,2), (6,3), (6,4), (6,5) <strong>and</strong> (6,9) according to the tax structure in the national<br />

Macro SAM documented in Tarp et. al. (2002).<br />

Cell (6,7) “Prov. Goverment-Central Government”: Transfer<br />

GSO (2002) documents the total transfer from the central government to each province. For<br />

11 regions this entry is derived by deducting cells (2,7), (4,7), (5,7), (8,7) <strong>and</strong> (9,7) from the total<br />

transfer from central government. In three cases (Lang Son, Phu Tho <strong>and</strong> Quang Ninh) the total<br />

transfer from the central government to each province enters directly in the individual Macro SAMs.<br />

Cell (6,9) “Prov. Government-ROW”: Net foreign transfers to state<br />

This entry is derived by using the provincial budget data provided by GSO (2002) for each<br />

region. Cell (6,9) include aid <strong>and</strong> grants. Furthermore “other revenue” in GSO (2002) was split upon<br />

cells (6,1), (6,2), (6,3), (6,4), (6,5) <strong>and</strong> (6,9) according to the tax structure in the national Macro SAM<br />

documented in Tarp et. al. (2002).<br />

Cell (7,1) “Central Government-Activities”: Value Added taxes<br />

For 11 regions this entry is derived by using the tax structure in the national Macro SAM<br />

documented in Tarp et. al. (2002) multiplied by net transfer from the central budget for each region.<br />

In three cases (Lang Son, Phu Tho <strong>and</strong> Quang Ninh) the tax shares is multiplied by total production<br />

taxes documented in GSO (2002).<br />

Cell (7,2) “Central Government-Commodities”: Trade taxes<br />

For 11 regions this entry is derived by using the tax structure in the national Macro SAM<br />

documented in Tarp et. al. (2002) multiplied by net transfer from the central budget for each region.<br />

In three cases (Lang Son, Phu Tho <strong>and</strong> Quang Ninh) the tax shares is multiplied by total production<br />

taxes documented in GSO (2002).<br />

Cell (7,3) “Central Government -Factors”: Factor taxes<br />

For 11 regions this entry is derived by using the tax structure in the national Macro SAM<br />

documented in Tarp et. al. (2002) multiplied by net transfer from the central budget for each region.<br />

In three cases (Lang Son, Phu Tho <strong>and</strong> Quang Ninh) the tax shares is multiplied by total production<br />

taxes documented in GSO (2002).<br />

Cell (7,4) “Central Government -Households”: <strong>Income</strong> taxes<br />

For 11 regions this entry is derived by using the tax structure in the national Macro SAM<br />

documented in Tarp et. al. (2002) multiplied by net transfer from the central budget for each region.<br />

In three cases (Lang Son, Phu Tho <strong>and</strong> Quang Ninh) the tax shares is multiplied by total production<br />

taxes documented in GSO (2002). In some of the regions additional adjustments of the income taxes<br />

had to done in order to secure balance of the regional Macro SAM.<br />

Cell (7,5) “Central Government -Enterprises”: Enterprise taxes<br />

Page 252


Appendix E: Details of MacroSAM construction<br />

For 11 regions this entry is derived by using the tax structure in the national Macro SAM<br />

documented in Tarp et. al. (2002) multiplied by net transfer from the central budget for each region.<br />

In three cases (Lang Son, Phu Tho <strong>and</strong> Quang Ninh) the tax shares is multiplied by total production<br />

taxes documented in GSO (2002). In some of the regions additional adjustments of the income taxes<br />

had to done in order to secure balance of the regional Macro SAM.<br />

Cell (7,6) “Central Government -Prov. Government”: Transfer<br />

Transfer to the central budget is documented in GSO (2002) for each region, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

information is used directly in the individual Macro SAMs.<br />

Cell (7,9) “Central Government -ROW”: Net foreign transfers to state<br />

For 11 regions this entry is derived by using the tax structure in the national Macro SAM<br />

documented in Tarp et. al. (2002) multiplied by net transfer from the central budget for each region.<br />

In three cases (Lang Son, Phu Tho <strong>and</strong> Quang Ninh) the tax shares is multiplied by total production<br />

taxes documented in GSO (2002).<br />

Cell (8,4) “Investment/Savings-Households”: Household savings<br />

Left in order to balance med regional Macro SAMs.<br />

Cell (8,5) “Investment/Savings-Enterprises”: Enterprise savings<br />

Left in order to balance med regional Macro SAMs.<br />

Cell (8,6) “Investment/Savings-Prov. Government”: Prov government savings<br />

Data on provincial government savings are reported by GSO (2002) for each region, <strong>and</strong> is<br />

derived by deducting expenditures for investment from total investment expenditures.<br />

Cell (8,7) “Investment/Savings-Central Government”: Central government savings<br />

Central government savings secure balance of the row <strong>and</strong> column totals of the capital<br />

account.<br />

Cell (9,2) “ROW-Commodities”: Imports<br />

GSO (2002) only reports net imports for each region. Using import shares of total output in<br />

the national Macro SAM documented in Tarp et. al. (2002) <strong>and</strong> applying this information to each<br />

region together with the region specific net import numbers, data on exports <strong>and</strong> imports for the 14<br />

regions becomes available.<br />

Cell (9,5) “ROW-Commodities”: Enterprise transfers abroad<br />

Left in order to balance med regional Macro SAMs.<br />

Cell (9,7) “ROW-Commodities”: Central Government transfers abroad<br />

Left in order to balance med regional Macro SAMs.<br />

Summing up, it can be noted that the accounts of the 14 regional Macro SAM balance. These tables,<br />

with few exceptions, are based entirely on official data supplied by GSO.<br />

Page 253


Appendix E: Details of MacroSAM Construction<br />

Page 254


Appendix E: Details of MacroSAM Construction<br />

Table A7.1: Vietnam Macro SAM, 2000 (Billion current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGovt CAPACC ROW Total<br />

ACT 852755 852755<br />

COM 427323 295993 28265 130827 241401 1123809<br />

FACT 376376 376376<br />

HH 270487 5553 42204 19842 338086<br />

ENT 105636 6245 1088 112969<br />

ProvGovt 0<br />

CentGovt 49056 19307 253 1840 25033 62854 2072 160415<br />

CAPACC 40253 77896 12678 130827<br />

ROW 251747 4487 8169 264403<br />

Total 852755 1123809 376376 338086 112969 0 160415 130827 264403 3359640<br />

Table A7.2: Provincial Aggregate Macro SAM, 2000 (Billion Current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGovt CAPACC ROW Total<br />

ACT 0 58776 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 58776<br />

COM 25863 0 0 22472 0 4276 3199 7732 16286 79827<br />

FACT 27120 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 27120<br />

HH 0 0 22407 0 383 531 2408 0 2984 28712<br />

ENT 0 0 4692 0 0 0 355 0 843 5891<br />

ProvGovt 2124 2256 1 19 332 0 2238 0 31 7002<br />

CentGovt 3669 1444 19 1588 1904 2154 0 0 155 10932<br />

CAPACC 0 0 0 4633 2662 41 395 0 0 7732<br />

ROW 0 17352 0 0 609 0 2337 0 0 20298<br />

Total 58776 79827 27120 28712 5891 7002 10932 7732 20298 246289


Table A7.3: Ha Giang: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 2139860 2139860<br />

COM 841287 746256 364362 152419 286700 556942 2947965<br />

FACT 983375 983375<br />

HH 848802 13934 28438 105905 46322 1043401<br />

ENT 133143 15671 14602 163416<br />

ProvGov 61767 76642 123 939 20158 297272 3151 460051<br />

CentGov 253431 99743 1307 9506 129324 67251 10704 571266<br />

CAPACC 286700 0 0 0 286700<br />

ROW 631721 0 0 631721<br />

Total 2139860 2947965 983375 1043401 163416 460051 571266 286700 631721 9227755<br />

Table A7.4: Cao Bang: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 2532876 2532876<br />

COM 908111 1112403 27468 240936 522867 608166 3419951<br />

FACT 1288370 1288370<br />

HH 1129396 16494 100359 125355 120404 1492009<br />

ENT 157473 18549 6602 182624<br />

ProvGov 80857 38757 183 1337 23183 8629 1780 154726<br />

CentGov 255539 100572 1318 9585 130400 24799 10793 533006<br />

CAPACC 368684 12547 2100 139536 522867<br />

ROW 747746 0 0 747746<br />

Total 2532876 3419951 1288370 1492009 182624 154726 533006 522867 747746 10874175


Table A7.5: Lao Cai: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH1 ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 2596951 2596951<br />

COM 963905 1258659 198680 142715 380470 621639 3566068<br />

FACT 1315787 1315787<br />

HH1 1034895 16911 109092 128527 125100 1414524<br />

ENT 279576 19018 6860 305454<br />

ProvGov 105645 119170 224 1632 30873 151767 4125 413436<br />

CentGov 211614 83285 1091 7937 107986 102048 8938 522900<br />

CAPACC 146296 149685 3616 80873 380470<br />

ROW 766662 0 0 766662<br />

Total 2596951 3566068 1315787 1414524 305454 413436 522900 380470 766662 11282252<br />

Table A7.6: Bac Kan: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 1032456 1032456<br />

COM 302748 384777 178652 65096 381645 107511 1420429<br />

FACT 494830 494830<br />

HH 448801 6723 109669 51098 120827 737118<br />

ENT 44939 7561 63842 116342<br />

ProvGov 25936 943 12 201 2997 258232 3792 292114<br />

CentGov 208941 82233 1078 7837 106622 0 8825 415536<br />

CAPACC 344303 0 3793 33549 381645<br />

ROW 304798 0 0 304798<br />

Total 1032456 1420429 494830 737118 116342 292114 415536 381645 304798 5195268


Table A7.7: Lang Son: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 3704406 3704406<br />

COM 1157420 1739702 674679 256079 532117 1288639 5648636<br />

FACT 2005842 2005842<br />

HH 1753374 24122 0 183336 167588 2128421<br />

ENT 250427 27129 9189 286745<br />

ProvGov 147476 695693 11 263 13563 514315 873 1372194<br />

CentGov 393668 154936 2030 14766 200886 694865 16628 1477779<br />

CAPACC 373690 48173 2650 107604 532117<br />

ROW 1093600 0 389317 1482917<br />

Total 3704406 5648636 2005842 2128421 286745 1372194 1477779 532117 1482917 18639057<br />

Table A7.8: Tuyen Quang: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 3052558 3052558<br />

COM 1109669 1623367 262935 169310 535451 356163 4056895<br />

FACT 1608636 1608636<br />

HH 1441739 19878 0 151075 434325 2047017<br />

ENT 165545 22355 98655 286555<br />

ProvGov 102408 11925 156 1275 28695 118346 2229 265035<br />

CentGov 231845 91247 1196 8696 118309 0 9793 461086<br />

CAPACC 413679 119672 2100 0 535451<br />

ROW 901164 0 0 901164<br />

Total 3052558 4056895 1608636 2047017 286555 265035 461086 535451 901164 13214397


Table A7.9: Yen Bai: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH1 ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 3156895 3156895<br />

COM 1245656 1125395 156727 288700 394944 967655 4179077<br />

FACT 1554125 1554125<br />

HH1 1332637 20557 0 128189 0 1481383<br />

ENT 220306 18968 6133 245408<br />

ProvGov 137956 3962 52 452 13304 0 2424 158149<br />

CentGov 219158 86254 1130 8220 111835 3 9257 435857<br />

CAPACC 347315 46210 1419 0 394944<br />

ROW 931966 53502 0 985469<br />

Total 3156895 4179077 1554125 1481383 245408 158149 435857 394944 985469 12591306<br />

Table A7.10: Thai Nguyen: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 6192896 6192896<br />

COM 3272174 2334965 222967 278776 651915 1339814 8100611<br />

FACT 2545795 2545795<br />

HH 2124071 40327 43016 39507 161340 2408260<br />

ENT 420683 4951 313812 739447<br />

ProvGov 212397 15505 203 2010 31263 0 6412 267790<br />

CentGov 162530 63967 838 6096 82938 0 6865 323234<br />

CAPACC 65190 584918 1807 0 651915<br />

ROW 1828243 0 0 1828243<br />

Total 6192896 8100611 2545795 2408260 739447 267790 323234 651915 1828243 23058191


Table A7.11: Phu Tho: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH1 ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 8717612 8717612<br />

COM 4808817 2621610 668777 410314 1326500 1589506 11425524<br />

FACT 3553973 3553973<br />

HH1 2694998 56768 0 431446 961949 4145161<br />

ENT 858174 63842 52747 974763<br />

ProvGov 219184 80950 102 2373 57356 382718 1133 743815<br />

CentGov 135638 53383 700 918382 101301 73188 5729 1288320<br />

CAPACC 602796 721854 1850 0 1326500<br />

ROW 2573579 37483 0 2611063<br />

Total 8717612 11425524 3553973 4145161 974763 743815 1288320 1326500 2611063 34786730<br />

Table A7.12: Bac Giang: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 5921066 5921066<br />

COM 2211390 3003601 163594 284968 757321 1370378 7791252<br />

FACT 3381985 3381985<br />

HH 2892571 38557 0 117350 168208 3216685<br />

ENT 488335 17364 199403 705102<br />

ProvGov 136716 47029 94 1174 19939 0 1940 206891<br />

CentGov 190976 75163 985 7163 97454 39875 8066 419682<br />

CAPACC 204747 549152 3422 0 757321<br />

ROW 1747994 0 0 1747994<br />

Total 5921066 7791252 3381985 3216685 705102 206891 419682 757321 1747994 24147978


Table A7.13: Quang Ninh: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 11245427 11245427<br />

COM 6178212 2777085 852792 346850 487805 5384630 16027374<br />

FACT 3717033 3717033<br />

HH 2562385 73228 88207 556551 320118 3600490<br />

ENT 1150566 82354 17553 1250473<br />

ProvGov 578743 1158499 103 6276 66633 288569 845 2099668<br />

CentGov 771440 303616 3979 565893 393661 1150628 32584 3221800<br />

CAPACC 251236 228528 8041 0 487805<br />

ROW 3319831 488422 1947476 5755730<br />

Total 11245427 16027374 3717033 3600490 1250473 2099668 3221800 487805 5755730 47405800<br />

Table A7.14: Lai Chau: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 2298205 2298205<br />

COM 862610 1125826 182441 145370 260020 472376 3048643<br />

FACT 1158587 1158587<br />

HH 1024235 14966 0 113741 156105 1309047<br />

ENT 133423 16830 42281 192535<br />

ProvGov 99395 2067 13 168 5005 78367 203 185219<br />

CentGov 177613 69903 916 6662 90635 1078 7502 354309<br />

CAPACC 176391 81929 1700 0 260020<br />

ROW 678467 0 0 678467<br />

Total 2298205 3048643 1158587 1309047 192535 185219 354309 260020 678467 9485032


Table A7.15: Son La: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 3007295 3007295<br />

COM 898697 1418810 198122 140478 576570 759020 3991696<br />

FACT 1758267 1758267<br />

HH 1612294 19583 51819 148835 111090 1943622<br />

ENT 144708 22023 6091 172823<br />

ProvGov 106732 726 9 499 7064 139518 1312 255860<br />

CentGov 243599 95873 1256 9137 124307 49 10289 484511<br />

CAPACC 515175 21868 5870 33657 576570<br />

ROW 887802 0 0 887802<br />

Total 3007295 3991696 1758267 1943622 172823 255860 484511 576570 887802 13078446<br />

Table A7.16: Hoa Binh: Provincial Macro SAM 2000 (Million current VND)<br />

ACT COM FACT HH ENT ProvGovt CentGov CAPACC ROW Col Total<br />

ACT 3177318 3177318<br />

COM 1102453 1199561 123863 276858 637280 863229 4203244<br />

FACT 1752986 1752986<br />

HH 1506715 20690 0 127144 90367 1744916<br />

ENT 245119 18814 4955 268888<br />

ProvGov 109277 4257 56 489 12149 0 457 126684<br />

CentGov 212602 83674 1096 7974 108490 0 8980 422816<br />

CAPACC 536892 97567 2821 0 637280<br />

ROW 937996 29993 0 967988<br />

Total 3177318 4203244 1752986 1744916 268888 126684 422816 637280 967988 13302122


Page 263


JAPAN BANK FOR INTERNATIONAL<br />

COOPERATION<br />

4-1, Ohtemachi 1-Chome, Chiyoda-ku<br />

Tokyo 100-8144 Japan<br />

T +81-3-5218-3101<br />

F +81-3-5218-3955<br />

W www.jbic.go.jp<br />

INTERNATIONAL FOOD POLICY<br />

RESEARCH INSTITUTE<br />

2033 K Street NW<br />

Washington, DC 20006-1002 USA<br />

T +1-202-862-5600<br />

F +1-202-467-4439<br />

E ifpri@cgiar.org<br />

W www.ifpri.org<br />

Copyright © 2003<br />

Japan Bank for International Cooperation &<br />

International Food Policy Research Institute<br />

All rights reserved.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!