15.05.2015 Views

A Cost-Benefit Analysis of Rural Secondary School Consolidation

A Cost-Benefit Analysis of Rural Secondary School Consolidation

A Cost-Benefit Analysis of Rural Secondary School Consolidation

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

A <strong>Cost</strong>-<strong>Benefit</strong> <strong>Analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Rural</strong> <strong>Secondary</strong> <strong>School</strong><br />

<strong>Consolidation</strong>: A Report To Gwynedd County<br />

Council<br />

James Foreman-Peck<br />

Welsh Institute for Research and Development<br />

Cardiff Business <strong>School</strong><br />

April2011


A <strong>Cost</strong>-<strong>Benefit</strong> <strong>Analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Rural</strong> <strong>Secondary</strong> <strong>School</strong> <strong>Consolidation</strong><br />

Contents<br />

Page<br />

Executive Summary 4<br />

1. Introduction 6<br />

2. Measurement Issues 7<br />

3. <strong>Cost</strong> per Pupil and <strong>School</strong> Size 7<br />

4. ‘Empty Places’ and <strong>Cost</strong> per Student 9<br />

5. Increased Student Travel Time 9<br />

6. Additional Vehicle Operating <strong>Cost</strong>s 11<br />

7. Local Incomes and Employment 12<br />

8. Disposal <strong>of</strong> <strong>School</strong> Site 14<br />

9. Educational Achievement and <strong>School</strong> Size 14<br />

10. Summary 16<br />

Appendix A Gwynedd secondary school cost functions 2002-2010 18<br />

Appendix B Pupil travel costs and times for incremental travel costing 20<br />

2


List <strong>of</strong> Tables<br />

Page<br />

Table 1 <strong>Benefit</strong>s and <strong>Cost</strong>s from <strong>School</strong> <strong>Consolidation</strong> 6<br />

Table 2 Ancillary Staff <strong>Cost</strong>s: An Illustration for a Small Gwynedd <strong>Secondary</strong><br />

<strong>School</strong> 13<br />

Table 3 Estimated <strong>Cost</strong>s and <strong>Benefit</strong>s from <strong>Rural</strong> <strong>Secondary</strong> <strong>School</strong> <strong>Consolidation</strong><br />

16<br />

Table A1 Per pupil Gwynedd secondary school panel cost functions 2002-2010<br />

19<br />

List <strong>of</strong> figures<br />

Figure 1 Budget cost per pupil in relation to school size, Wales 2009-10 8<br />

Figure 2 Gwynedd school size and KS3 performance 22<br />

Figure 3 Gwynedd secondary school size and predicted pupil cost 22<br />

Figure 4 Gwynedd school predicted pupil cost and KS3 performance 23<br />

3


A <strong>Cost</strong>-<strong>Benefit</strong> <strong>Analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Rural</strong> <strong>Secondary</strong> <strong>School</strong> <strong>Consolidation</strong><br />

Executive Summary<br />

1. This cost-benefit analysis <strong>of</strong> rural secondary school consolidation<br />

aims to take into account all the major relevant social and economic<br />

impacts <strong>of</strong> the policy in accordance with H M Treasury guidelines. As<br />

Treasury documentation makes clear in the context <strong>of</strong> central<br />

government, an education authority focus exclusively on financial<br />

outlays is not required by the pursuit <strong>of</strong> efficiency and effectiveness<br />

on behalf <strong>of</strong> the taxpayer when the authority has other policies and<br />

obligations to take into consideration as well.<br />

2. A hypothetical example is studied in which a rural secondary school<br />

<strong>of</strong> 350 pupils is closed and the students distributed to two others,<br />

one a school initially also <strong>of</strong> 350 and one initially <strong>of</strong> 500. This<br />

reconfiguration can be expected to reduce authority financial costs<br />

per pupil and ‘empty places’. But it does so by imposing other costs<br />

on the authority through its obligations to provide more transport<br />

for the students who must now travel greater distances.<br />

3. In addition greater costs are imposed upon the pupils, who must<br />

spend more time travelling. Standard UK transport project appraisal<br />

procedures value such extra time saved or spent and therefore<br />

consistency in the allocation <strong>of</strong> public funds requires that school<br />

consolidation policies should do so as well.<br />

4. A third cost imposed by the hypothetical school closure is a loss <strong>of</strong><br />

local income and employment- with the attendant social disruption.<br />

While the relocation may be expected to benefit income and<br />

employment in other local communities, the authority may not<br />

consider this redistribution as consistent with their social policies.<br />

5. On the benefit side <strong>of</strong> the policy balance there may be educational<br />

pay<strong>of</strong>fs for students in larger schools <strong>of</strong> the size considered here. An<br />

attempt is made to estimate their monetary value – that is how<br />

much extra must be spent to obtain equivalent educational<br />

performance in the school configuration before the hypothetical<br />

consolidation, compared with how much after. Even more<br />

4


uncertainty is attached to the disposal value <strong>of</strong> the hypothetical<br />

school site. Therefore a sensitivity analysis is conducted to see what<br />

values are sufficient to tip the net benefit balance between positive<br />

and negative.<br />

6. The conclusion <strong>of</strong> the study is that comparing the above costs and<br />

benefits, calculated on as plausible and as robust assumptions as<br />

possible, yields a negative balance from the hypothetical school<br />

closure. What this means is that the authority would not be obliged<br />

on grounds <strong>of</strong> efficiency and effectiveness to close the rural school.<br />

However, if for example, the authority decided that it was<br />

appropriate to shift the full costs <strong>of</strong> educational provision more on<br />

to students and away from the taxpayer, it might chose to do so, at<br />

least if other policies affecting the remaining components <strong>of</strong> the<br />

cost-benefit analysis also pointed to such a decision.<br />

5


A <strong>Cost</strong>-<strong>Benefit</strong> <strong>Analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Rural</strong> <strong>Secondary</strong> <strong>School</strong> <strong>Consolidation</strong><br />

1. Introduction<br />

This report is an appraisal, broadly following the guidelines laid down in HM<br />

Treasury's Green Book, <strong>of</strong> secondary school closure policy. The Welsh Assembly<br />

Government is signed up to following this Treasury guidance on project and<br />

programme appraisal and evaluation. Although the guidance refers to ‘central<br />

government’, local authorities are mainly funded from the centre, and therefore<br />

the use <strong>of</strong> the same principles for ensuring effectiveness, efficiency and economy<br />

in public spending makes sense.<br />

The Treasury states that the Green Book principles are relevant<br />

‘to any analysis used to support a government decision to adopt a new policy, or<br />

to initiate, renew, expand or re-orientate programmes or projects, which would<br />

result in measurable benefits and/ or costs to the public.’ (S1.8)<br />

The guidance recommends procedures for cost-benefit analysis – in particular for<br />

valuations <strong>of</strong> outcomes. This involves taking into consideration wider social<br />

impacts as well as immediate financial outlays and savings.<br />

‘Wider social and environmental costs and benefits for which there is no market<br />

price also need to be brought into any assessment. They will <strong>of</strong>ten be more<br />

difficult to assess but are <strong>of</strong>ten important and should not be ignored simply<br />

because they cannot easily be costed’. (s5.12)<br />

Such social costs and benefits might include quality <strong>of</strong> educational provision, as<br />

well as the educational experience <strong>of</strong> the pupil in the wider sense such as travel<br />

time, length <strong>of</strong> day, and safety.<br />

The present report considers the following cost and benefits <strong>of</strong> rural secondary<br />

school consolidation;<br />

Table 1 <strong>Benefit</strong>s and <strong>Cost</strong>s from <strong>School</strong> <strong>Consolidation</strong><br />

<strong>Benefit</strong>s<br />

<strong>Cost</strong>s<br />

Lower school cost per Greater student travel<br />

pupil<br />

times<br />

Lower cost per level <strong>of</strong> Greater student travel<br />

education achievement costs<br />

Redundant school site Loss <strong>of</strong> rural community<br />

disposal<br />

income and employment<br />

6


2. Measurement Issues<br />

To weigh costs against benefits <strong>of</strong> secondary school consolidation both must be<br />

in comparable time units and preferable valued in monetary terms.<br />

Conventionally magnitudes are capitalised into present values but the present<br />

study instead considers annual flows <strong>of</strong> benefits and costs. It does so because<br />

education provision is a permanent obligation (there is no project end point) and<br />

because projecting costs and benefits into the future creates additional<br />

uncertainties and margins <strong>of</strong> error, which it is judged desirable to do without. So<br />

implicitly this exercise assumes that conditions this year will continue into the<br />

future.<br />

While financial outlays are readily available, other costs and benefits are less<br />

easily measured in monetary terms, which may explain, but not justify, why<br />

they are <strong>of</strong>ten ignored in assessing the merits <strong>of</strong> a policy. In the case <strong>of</strong> travel<br />

time, (English) Department <strong>of</strong> Transport estimates are widely used. But the<br />

value <strong>of</strong> a local community or <strong>of</strong> the quality <strong>of</strong> educational provision is more<br />

problematic. On occasion, as will be shown below, an analysis allows these<br />

intangibles to be treated as residuals so that values at which the policy decision<br />

would be altered can be calculated, and compared with policy makers’<br />

judgements.<br />

3. <strong>Cost</strong> per Pupil and <strong>School</strong> Size<br />

The apparent financial advantages <strong>of</strong> school consolidation are illustrated by<br />

figure 1. Each cross represents a particular school. The figure shows the fall in<br />

costs per pupil with secondary school size in Wales in 2010. There is a<br />

substantial scatter around the line <strong>of</strong> best fit because other school characteristics<br />

may influence costs, as well as size. But the relationship is helpful because<br />

secondary schools in Gwynedd are close to this Welsh average line.<br />

Suppose a school <strong>of</strong> 350 pupils was closed, and 150 <strong>of</strong> those students went to<br />

another school <strong>of</strong> similar size, raising numbers to 500. The remaining 200<br />

students travel to a school that originally educated 500, but is now expanded to<br />

700. The figure shows that around £200 a student is saved by putting the 150 in<br />

7


the school <strong>of</strong> now 500 students. But also the costs <strong>of</strong> educating those 350<br />

original students in the now expanded school are cut by around £200 a student.<br />

This element <strong>of</strong> the consolidation then saves £100,000. The gains from the<br />

consolidation with the larger school are greater. On the 200 students moved<br />

there around £500 a head is saved. The costs <strong>of</strong> educating the 500 students<br />

already attending larger schools also fall by perhaps £300. The ostensible<br />

financial total saved by this rationalisation amounts to about £350,000 or £1000<br />

per pupil.<br />

Figure 1 Budget cost per pupil in relation to school size, Wales 2009-10<br />

In Appendix A are average cost functions estimated for Gwynedd secondary<br />

schools between 2002 and 2010. The calculation with the parameters <strong>of</strong> the<br />

preferred equation yields about the same conclusion as above; that the<br />

immediate financial savings from the hypothetical consolidation would be about<br />

£1000 per affected student. Taking into account proportions <strong>of</strong> pupils entitled to<br />

free school meals, numbers in sixth forms and percentages not achieving any<br />

qualifications, does not significantly affect the results.<br />

8


4. ‘Empty Places’ and <strong>Cost</strong> per Student<br />

Education authority cost per pupil cannot be the sole index <strong>of</strong> efficiency or school<br />

performance. A school delivering a better education may be more expensive<br />

than another, but it is not necessarily less efficient; it may be worthwhile<br />

incurring higher costs for a ‘better’ school. Conversely it is not necessarily fair<br />

simply if all state schools incur the same costs per pupil. A pupil may receive<br />

different standards <strong>of</strong> education depending on the state school attended.<br />

Similar considerations apply to the idea <strong>of</strong> ‘empty (school) places’. This is a short<br />

run (with given school buildings and staff) equivalent <strong>of</strong> the cost per pupil<br />

indicator. If a school can take more students with the same resources, the<br />

financial cost per student falls – which in itself is clearly desirable. But as an<br />

over-riding goal <strong>of</strong> education policy it can be misleading. If students do not want<br />

to attend a particular school for good reason, such as the quality <strong>of</strong> education or<br />

the distance required to travel, it is likely to be an error to focus solely on filling<br />

the empty places – rather than for instance improving school quality.<br />

Demographic change may give rise to ‘empty places’ at particular schools but it<br />

does not necessarily follow that such schools must be closed or that students<br />

should be bussed in from elsewhere. The purpose <strong>of</strong> policy appraisal is to judge<br />

whether it is. Ultimately the elected authority must make decisions about the<br />

distribution <strong>of</strong> all the benefits and costs <strong>of</strong> school consolidation or maintaining<br />

the status quo with the best available information about their magnitudes.<br />

A school consolidation policy may be expected to increase travel time costs<br />

imposed upon students in exchange for a lower financial burden for the<br />

taxpayer. Even when the financial savings exceed the time costs, the authority is<br />

not obliged to conclude the policy, on these grounds, is desirable. It is only<br />

appropriate to do so if the outcome is consistent with their other objectives and<br />

policies<br />

5. Increased Student Travel Time<br />

What are the wider social and economic costs and benefits? Some are easier to<br />

quantify than others. These include greater pupil travel costs. When the<br />

(English) Department <strong>of</strong> Transport appraises priorities for road improvements<br />

9


the principal benefits that they weigh against the outlays are travel time and<br />

costs and safety. They have developed procedures for measuring these in<br />

various circumstances (Department <strong>of</strong> Transport 2009).<br />

‘The majority <strong>of</strong> journeys ... take place .... in the traveller’s own time. However,<br />

people implicitly put a value on their own time, in that they will trade a cheaper,<br />

slower journey against a faster, more expensive one.’ (1.2.11)<br />

In their guidance the Department <strong>of</strong> Transport note their valuations in their<br />

Table 2 includes those <strong>of</strong> retired people.<br />

It might be questioned whether non-earning school students should be treated<br />

as equivalent to retired persons. The democratic principles under-pinning <strong>Cost</strong>-<br />

<strong>Benefit</strong> <strong>Analysis</strong> imply that for present purposes there is no reason to treat<br />

young people and children differently from adults, economically active or retired.<br />

As the Transport department explain;<br />

If values <strong>of</strong> time for appraisal are based on an individual’s willingness to pay<br />

which are related to income, then strategies and plans will be biased towards<br />

those measures which most benefit travellers with higher incomes ...Investment<br />

will then be concentrated into high-income areas, and the interests <strong>of</strong> those on<br />

lower incomes, who may already suffer from relatively lower mobility and<br />

accessibility, will be given less weight. For this reason, multimodal transport<br />

appraisal should normally adopt the values for non-working time which is<br />

common across all modes and journey purposes.’(s1.2.14)<br />

In short, the journey to and from school should not be appraised any differently<br />

from other non-work trips.<br />

The 2002 value recommended by the English Department for Transport for noncommuting<br />

leisure travel time is £4.46 per hour. Uprating the leisure travel time<br />

to 2011values takes the figure over £5 an hour. Students travel for about 5<br />

days a week for 40 weeks a year – say 188 days. To how much extra travelling<br />

time are students committed with a school re-organisation? In relatively sparsely<br />

populated rural areas the position can be markedly different from in cities. There<br />

is some evidence that an extra 20 minutes each way (Appendix B) could be<br />

imposed on the average former pupil <strong>of</strong> a closed hypothetical school. If this were<br />

so, then conventional cost-benefit analysis registers a cost in the hypothetical<br />

10


example <strong>of</strong> the 350 students considered earlier, <strong>of</strong>;<br />

350x(40/60)x5x188˜£220,000 each year.<br />

6. Additional Vehicle Operating <strong>Cost</strong>s<br />

In addition to these extra time costs, there are those associated with the<br />

vehicles operation. Estimating these costs requires knowledge <strong>of</strong> how many<br />

students travel by bus, by car, by bicycle or by foot, as well as the distances <strong>of</strong><br />

each. Obviously the mix will change from year to year so only an average or<br />

approximation is possible. In order to get a downward biased idea <strong>of</strong> the extra<br />

vehicle costs, assume all the students travel the extra distance by bus (cheaper<br />

than private cars in cost-benefit analysis). In 2009/10 bus operating costs per<br />

kilometre in Wales were 114 pence (DfT Bus). If the same number <strong>of</strong> buses<br />

could carry the extra student the marginal costs <strong>of</strong> the present exercise would<br />

be zero, but, in the long run at least, certainly more buses would need to be laid<br />

on and the marginal costs would be positive.<br />

If 200 <strong>of</strong> the 350 hypothetical students’ journeys required more buses, with an<br />

extra average journey per day to and from school <strong>of</strong> 20 kilometres say, and an<br />

average bus occupancy <strong>of</strong> 8, the extra vehicle costs per year would be<br />

£200x20x200x1.14/8˜£110,000<br />

An alternative exercise based upon detailed consideration <strong>of</strong> particular schools,<br />

yields an annual cost larger by almost one half. The exercise as before focuses<br />

on closing one 11-16 <strong>Secondary</strong> school <strong>of</strong> 350 students. Pupils would transfer to<br />

two other <strong>Secondary</strong> schools depending on where they live. Pupils are assumed<br />

to attend their nearest school. In Appendix B are the estimates <strong>of</strong> the length <strong>of</strong><br />

the journey travelled and the travelling times.<br />

<strong>Cost</strong>s are based upon the use <strong>of</strong> buses (Arriva trains are not willing to put extra<br />

carriages on their trains at present). Single deck buses must be run because the<br />

Assembly are at present considering the abolition <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> double-decker<br />

buses for school transport.<br />

Total cost <strong>of</strong> transporting pupils to their two new schools as described in the<br />

Appendix: £270,000<br />

11


Present costs <strong>of</strong> transporting pupils to school considered for closure by bus and<br />

train from catchment area primary schools: £107,166.<br />

Implementing the closure according to the above model therefore increases<br />

travel costs by<br />

£162,834 per annum,<br />

a considerably higher figure than the first, rather abstract, exercise.<br />

7. Local Incomes and Employment<br />

‘Proposals might have differential impacts on individuals, amongst other<br />

aspects, according to their:... geographical location.. It is important that these<br />

distributional issues are assessed in appraisals.’ H M Treasury Green Book<br />

(2003) Annex 5 s.1 p.91<br />

In addition to the obligation to ensure that expenditure is efficient and effective,<br />

spending authorities are advised to take into consideration the distributional<br />

consequences <strong>of</strong> policies, programmes and projects.<br />

<strong>Rural</strong> secondary school consolidation undoubtedly impacts upon local<br />

employment and income, in view <strong>of</strong> the distances between schools and the low<br />

incomes and part-time work <strong>of</strong> much ancillary employment. Part-time and low<br />

income workers are less likely to find it financially feasible to travel substantial<br />

distances to work regularly. Consequently, rural school closure would certainly<br />

deprive local cleaners, catering assistants, maintenance staff, lunchtime<br />

supervisors and probably classroom support workers, <strong>of</strong> sources <strong>of</strong> income.<br />

Their pay and numbers in a particular case are given in Table 2.<br />

It is true that the area in which the expanded schools are located would benefit<br />

from greater income and employment opportunities as a result <strong>of</strong> school<br />

consolidation. But authorities may not regard this redistribution as in accordance<br />

with their policies. They are not obliged to treat losses to some people as <strong>of</strong>fset<br />

by gains to others – even when the magnitudes are balanced – if a major policy<br />

concern, such as maintaining rural communities, was involved.<br />

To estimate how much income and employment might be involved each year in<br />

a rural secondary school closure, it is probably appropriate to assume teaching<br />

and more highly paid ancillary staff would be able to commute. Though this<br />

12


imposes an additional cost upon them, if they lived locally their job relocations<br />

would not much affect local incomes and employment.<br />

Taking the following ancillary staff costs (Table 2) as illustrative, even excluding<br />

the classroom assistants and those earning more than approximately £7000, the<br />

low and part-time incomes in the locality would be cut by about £74,000 a year<br />

in the event <strong>of</strong> school closure. The spending <strong>of</strong> the affected people would also<br />

support other employment – though judging by a study <strong>of</strong> Welsh National Parks<br />

this multiplier effect is small. The National Parks Study (National Trust 2006)<br />

estimated across all three parks an extra 20 percent <strong>of</strong> indirect income and<br />

within the Parks perhaps an extra 2 percent. These numbers justify adding a<br />

little on to the illustrative £74,000. The margins <strong>of</strong> uncertainty as to how much<br />

to add are considerable so here the figure is simply rounded up to £75,000 to<br />

include multiplier effects.<br />

Table 2 Ancillary Staff <strong>Cost</strong>s: An Illustration for a Small Gwynedd<br />

<strong>Secondary</strong> <strong>School</strong><br />

Take Home Pay:<br />

1 Administrative Officer £26,276<br />

2 Receptionist £10,581<br />

3 Library/Resources Assistant £9,273<br />

4 Science Technician £13,608<br />

5 IT Technician £10,917<br />

6 Learning Coach/Admin £16,538<br />

7 Caretaker £16,830<br />

8 Clerk <strong>of</strong> Governors £1,750<br />

9 Senior Supervisors (x2) £26,748<br />

10 Classroom Support Workers (x11) £107,652<br />

11 Kitchen Staff (x5) £33,261<br />

12 Cleaners (x5) £21,072<br />

13 Lunchtime Supervisors (x4) £6,035<br />

Total Staff = 35 £300,541<br />

+ Grounds Maintenance Contract<br />

(held by a local Operator) £12,000<br />

Total = £312,541<br />

13


8. Disposal <strong>of</strong> <strong>School</strong> Site<br />

When a small Primary school building becomes available, it is first <strong>of</strong>fered for<br />

community use and then in the absence <strong>of</strong> takers, placed on the open market.<br />

The building might be an pportunity for a small business premises, or a local<br />

developer might, subject to planning permission, use the site to build houses.<br />

<strong>Secondary</strong> school sites are, however, large and complex, with laboratories,<br />

gymnasiums, halls and other unusual features. They might be attractive for<br />

large developments such as supermarkets but there would otherwise be limited<br />

demands for the site in a rural community. Local developers would not be so<br />

easily attracted and any large housing development would not be popular or<br />

needed- and therefore would not be granted planning permission. The site could<br />

become a liability rather than an asset, especially in the short term.<br />

If demolition had to be considered, then these costs could be high. Some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

rural schools are also within the National Park which would present considerable<br />

planning issues for any new developments. By contrast, if a school in one <strong>of</strong> the<br />

more urban areas was considered for closure then there would be a possibility <strong>of</strong><br />

substantial gains.<br />

Since the present study estimates annual costs and benefits rather than present<br />

values, any sum from sale <strong>of</strong> the site must be converted into an annual figure.<br />

At the 3.5 percent real discount rate recommended by the Treasury, for every<br />

£100,000 <strong>of</strong> the net value <strong>of</strong> the site sold, the annual value would be £3,500.<br />

9. Educational Achievement and <strong>School</strong> Size<br />

There is evidence that many Welsh secondary schools are larger than desirable<br />

for the best educational performance (Foreman-Peck and Foreman-Peck 2006).<br />

However, schools in Gwynedd are generally below, close to, or not far above this<br />

calculated optimum. A scatter plot (figure 2) <strong>of</strong> the relationship since 2002<br />

between school size in Gwynedd and school Key stage 3 percentage score shows<br />

no relationship between the variables. On the other hand there is a relationship<br />

between school size and per pupil cost (as predicted by equation 1 Table A1)<br />

(figure 3). And the (predicted) costs per pupil appear to rise with KS3 score<br />

14


performance (figure 4). At first sight then it would seem that funding is allocated<br />

to schools so that they may maintain a target educational standard regardless <strong>of</strong><br />

their size. There appears to be no size penalty once the higher running costs <strong>of</strong><br />

small schools are taken into account.<br />

However, there is evidence <strong>of</strong> a cost penalty for achieving a given school Key<br />

Stage 3 educational standard for schools <strong>of</strong> the size <strong>of</strong> the example considered<br />

throughout this study – 350 pupils - from estimated costs function for Gwynedd<br />

schools. The interpretation <strong>of</strong> this result is not entirely clear. Ideally an<br />

educational value added measure would be related to school costs, but<br />

experiments with the %tl2 score and KS3 did not yield statistically significant<br />

results.<br />

With the KS3 score alone the results appear to show that the cost <strong>of</strong> achieving a<br />

given KS3 score not only decline with school size but are actually negative over<br />

the range <strong>of</strong> pupils 300+. This raises questions as to what the KS3 score is<br />

actually measuring. A possibility is that it is measuring an input into secondary<br />

education rather than an output; perhaps it captures the achievements <strong>of</strong><br />

students arriving from primary schools. If it does then the possibility that<br />

achieving a given standard <strong>of</strong> education is cheaper the higher the attainments<br />

<strong>of</strong> the new students makes sense, but does not indicate stronger performance <strong>of</strong><br />

larger schools and an additional disadvantage <strong>of</strong> smaller schools. But the cost<br />

functions reported in Appendix A table A1 show negative coefficient on the<br />

interaction between school size and KS3 score. One interpretation is that larger<br />

schools have catchment areas with higher achieving pupil intakes in Gwynedd.<br />

The number <strong>of</strong> schools is sufficiently small that it is not possible to distinguish<br />

this possibility from the negative marginal or average costs <strong>of</strong> KS3 score with<br />

size option.<br />

It turns out, in any case, that the apparent size penalty for achieving a given<br />

percentage KS3 score is small (Appendix A). According to the preferred equation<br />

the lower cost <strong>of</strong> achieving a given KS3 score with the larger school<br />

configuration amounts to merely £3700.<br />

15


10. Summary<br />

The estimated cost and benefits <strong>of</strong> the hypothetical rural secondary school<br />

consolidation are shown in Table 3 below (columns a). All <strong>of</strong> the figures in the<br />

Table are surrounded by a substantial margin <strong>of</strong> uncertainty. In the case <strong>of</strong><br />

school site disposal it is hard to arrive at a figure other than zero at all.<br />

However, with other the numbers in the table, a site net value <strong>of</strong> £2 million,<br />

when converted into a permanent annual value to be commensurate with the<br />

other figures, would not be sufficient to turn the balance <strong>of</strong> net benefits from<br />

consolidation positive in the best estimate case <strong>of</strong> columns a.<br />

Table 3 Estimated <strong>Cost</strong>s and <strong>Benefit</strong>s from <strong>Rural</strong> <strong>Secondary</strong> <strong>School</strong> <strong>Consolidation</strong><br />

<strong>Benefit</strong>s p.a. £ <strong>Cost</strong>s p.a. £<br />

a b a b<br />

Lower school<br />

costs<br />

360,000 500,000 Greater<br />

student travel<br />

220,000 220,000<br />

Lower cost per<br />

level <strong>of</strong><br />

education<br />

achievement<br />

Redundant<br />

school site<br />

disposal<br />

times<br />

3,700 3,700 Greater<br />

student vehicle<br />

costs<br />

0? 35,000 Loss <strong>of</strong> rural<br />

community<br />

income and<br />

employment<br />

160,000 160,000<br />

75,000 185,000<br />

Totals 363,700 538,700 455,000 565,000<br />

Balance <strong>Benefit</strong>


determine the appropriate policy, not concerns with ‘empty places’ or ‘cost per<br />

pupil’.<br />

True efficiency involves achieving desired objectives with the least possible<br />

resource cost. It is important to recognise that there is usually more than one<br />

policy objective, more than one resource and that in these circumstances priority<br />

cannot always be claimed for policies that minimise cash outflows.<br />

References<br />

Department for Transport (2009) Transport <strong>Analysis</strong> Guidance Values <strong>of</strong> Time<br />

and Operating <strong>Cost</strong>s TAG Unit 3.5.6, April<br />

Department <strong>of</strong> Transport, Bus Operating <strong>Cost</strong>s<br />

www.dft.gov.uk/pgr/.../datatablespublications/public/bus/costs/bus0409.xls<br />

Foreman-Peck J and Foreman-Peck L (2006) Should schools be smaller? The<br />

size-performance relationship for Welsh schools. Economics <strong>of</strong> Education Review<br />

H M Treasury (2003) The Green Book, Appraisal and Evaluation in Central<br />

Government: Treasury Guidance, http://www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/d/green_book_complete.pdf<br />

National Trust (2006) Valuing our Environment: Economic Impact <strong>of</strong> the National<br />

Parks <strong>of</strong> Wales,<br />

http://www.nationalparks.gov.uk/voe_national_parks_summary_english.pdf<br />

17


Appendix A Gwynedd secondary school cost functions 2002-2010 *<br />

<strong>School</strong> costs per pupil (AC) are determined by wages (T, assumed to grow at a<br />

steady annual rate), staffing levels, school buildings, number <strong>of</strong> pupils (Q) and<br />

perhaps educational standards (<strong>School</strong> %Key stage 3 here, KS3). The following<br />

cost function is estimated from a panel <strong>of</strong> 14 schools 2002-2010, with the years<br />

2003-5 excluded.<br />

AC=a + bQ + cQ 2 + dKS3 + e KS3*Q + fT + .. + u<br />

Parameter restrictions; c, d, f>0, b


On top <strong>of</strong> this there is the gain on 200 students from moving from a school <strong>of</strong><br />

350 to one <strong>of</strong> 500, i.e. from the first calculation £267*200=£53,400. So the<br />

total financial cost reduction from school consolidation is ;<br />

134000+171200+53400 = £358,600,<br />

broadly similar to the £350,000 calculated by visual inspection <strong>of</strong> figure 1.<br />

Turning to school quality, the extra cost <strong>of</strong> achieving a given KS3 score from<br />

having smaller schools, or the lower costs <strong>of</strong> achieving a given KS3 score with<br />

the larger school configuration, must be calculated for the cost-benefit analysis.<br />

Again using Eq.1 Table A1, the cost reduction for the school ending up with 500<br />

students is; ? AC=-.0174*150= -2.61, with ? TC=1305<br />

For the 700 pupil school ?AC = -.0174*200 =-3.48, with ? TC=-2436<br />

Therefore total quality incremental cost is merely £3700.<br />

Table A1 Per pupil Gwynedd secondary school panel cost functions 2002-2010<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6<br />

AC AC AC1 AC1 AC AC<br />

Q pupils -2.0987*** -3.2901*** -2.5656** -4.7004*** -3.2569*** -2.0909***<br />

Q 2 0.0016*** 0.0017*** 0.0022*** 0.0024*** 0.0017*** 0.0015***<br />

ks3 7.2164** 7.1792** 9.1834* 8.9295 -1.9e+03** -1.8e+03**<br />

ks3*Q -0.0174*** -0.0155*** -0.0266*** -0.0217** -0.0150*** -0.0167***<br />

T year 179.154*** 173.131*** 231.811*** 218.476*** 114.380*** 123.241***<br />

ks3*T - - - - 0.9579** 0.9067**<br />

constant -3.5e+05*** -3.4e+05*** -4.6e+05*** -4.3e+05*** -2.2e+05*** -2.4e+05***<br />

N 84 84 84 84 84 84<br />

r2_a 0.9567 0.9583 0.8954 0.8991 0.9622 0.9611<br />

fixed/random RE FE RE FE FE RE<br />

legend: * p


Appendix B<br />

Extra pupil travel costs and times for one <strong>of</strong> the incremental travel costings<br />

.....<br />

.....<br />

.....<br />

TOTAL: 217 pupils to be transported<br />

4 extra 50 seater buses needed.<br />

<strong>Cost</strong>: £120,000.<br />

20


Figure 2 Gwynedd school size and KS3 performance<br />

KS3 Performance (% Achieved CSI)<br />

20 40 60 80<br />

0 500 1000 1500<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> pupils<br />

21


Figure 3 Gwynedd secondary school size and predicted pupil cost<br />

Linear prediction<br />

2500 3000 3500 4000 4500 5000<br />

0 500 1000 1500<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> pupils<br />

22


Figure 4 Gwynedd school predicted pupil cost and KS3 performance<br />

Linear prediction<br />

2500 3000 3500 4000 4500 5000<br />

20 40 60 80<br />

KS3 Performance (% Achieved CSI)<br />

23

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!