17.11.2012 Views

CEO Age, Underinvestment, and Agency Costs - Department of ...

CEO Age, Underinvestment, and Agency Costs - Department of ...

CEO Age, Underinvestment, and Agency Costs - Department of ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong>, <strong>Underinvestment</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>Age</strong>ncy <strong>Costs</strong> *<br />

Matthew A. Serfling<br />

Eller College <strong>of</strong> Management<br />

University <strong>of</strong> Arizona<br />

Tucson, AZ 85721-0108<br />

serfling@email.arizona.edu<br />

(218) 244-7965<br />

February 2012<br />

Abstract:<br />

Prior theoretical work provides conflicting predictions with respect to how a <strong>CEO</strong>’s age impacts<br />

his investment decisions. I document that older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> that<br />

this finding is concentrated in firms with larger growth opportunities, suggesting an<br />

underinvestment problem. Further, when older <strong>CEO</strong>s make investments, they appear to make<br />

investments that reduce firm-specific risk. In addition, firms with older <strong>CEO</strong>s have lower sales<br />

<strong>and</strong> income growth <strong>and</strong> earn lower risk-adjusted stock returns. Counter to efficient contracting<br />

which would predict that older <strong>CEO</strong>s are provided with more equity-based performance sensitive<br />

compensation to mitigate underinvestment problems, I document that older <strong>CEO</strong>s actually<br />

receive less <strong>of</strong> this form <strong>of</strong> compensation but receive higher levels <strong>of</strong> cash compensation.<br />

Overall, my findings suggest that the age <strong>of</strong> a <strong>CEO</strong> can have an important effect on corporate<br />

financial policy choices, firm performance, <strong>and</strong> the existence <strong>of</strong> agency costs within a firm.<br />

* I thank S<strong>and</strong>y Klasa, Douglas Fairhurst, Ping Tan, J. Scott Judd, <strong>and</strong> participants at a doctoral student workshop at<br />

the University <strong>of</strong> Arizona for their helpful comments.


1. Introduction<br />

Because <strong>CEO</strong>s are the key decision makers in firms, there is interest in the role that<br />

unique <strong>CEO</strong> attributes play in explaining variation in corporate decisions across firms. Recent<br />

empirical work shows that <strong>CEO</strong>s’ corporate leverage decisions are related to their personal<br />

leverage decisions (Cronqvist, Makhija, <strong>and</strong> Yonker (2011)), that <strong>CEO</strong> overconfidence affects<br />

investment decisions (Malmendier, Tate, <strong>and</strong> Yan (2011)), that <strong>CEO</strong>s’ personal life experiences<br />

impact their attitudes toward risks (Malmendier <strong>and</strong> Nagel (2011)), <strong>and</strong> <strong>CEO</strong>s’ education levels<br />

affect the aggressiveness <strong>of</strong> their corporate strategies (Bertr<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Schoar (2003)).<br />

Prior theoretical work also predicts that an important <strong>CEO</strong> characteristic that can affect<br />

corporate decisions is a <strong>CEO</strong>’s age. Specifically, a <strong>CEO</strong>’s age can impact investment choices.<br />

Market learning models lead to predictions that younger <strong>CEO</strong>s invest less than older <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

because younger <strong>CEO</strong>s are more risk-averse since they do not have a previous record <strong>of</strong><br />

accomplishments, <strong>and</strong> as such, if they make a bad investment decision, this could markedly<br />

reduce their future career opportunities (e.g., Scharfstein <strong>and</strong> Stein (1990); Holmstrom (1999)).<br />

In contrast, managerial signaling models predict that older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest less aggressively<br />

compared to their younger counterparts, as younger <strong>CEO</strong>s try to signal superior ability to the<br />

market through more <strong>and</strong> bolder investments (e.g., Prendergast <strong>and</strong> Stole (1996)). Further, if<br />

older <strong>CEO</strong>s are more entrenched or have greater influence over the board, then such <strong>CEO</strong>s could<br />

get away with enjoying a quiet life, resulting in lower investment levels relative to younger<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s (e.g., Bertr<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Mullainathan (2003)).<br />

In this paper, I provide evidence on whether a <strong>CEO</strong>’s age affects his investment<br />

decisions. Further, I investigate whether in instances in which the effect <strong>of</strong> a <strong>CEO</strong>’s age on his<br />

investment decisions leads to decisions that could reduce shareholder value, if consistent with<br />

1


efficient contracting, firms take steps to mitigate this problem. I study firms listed on Execucomp<br />

between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 2010 <strong>and</strong> document that older <strong>CEO</strong>s are prone to invest less than younger<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s. To verify whether this finding is driven by a <strong>CEO</strong>’s age having a causal impact on his<br />

investment behavior, I examine changes in firm investment activity subsequent to the arrival <strong>of</strong> a<br />

new <strong>CEO</strong>. I find that when younger (older) <strong>CEO</strong>s are replaced by older (younger) <strong>CEO</strong>s, this<br />

leads to decreases (increases) in a firm’s investment level. These results are consistent with the<br />

prediction that older (younger) <strong>CEO</strong>s have less (more) aggressive investment styles.<br />

I also document that the difference in investment between older <strong>and</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s is<br />

concentrated in firms with above median level investment opportunities. This suggests that firms<br />

with important investment opportunities that are managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s could suffer from large<br />

underinvestment problems. Consistent with this notion, I find that sales growth is 6% lower <strong>and</strong><br />

operating income growth is 10% lower in firms that are run by <strong>CEO</strong>s in the top age tercile.<br />

Further indicating that this underinvestment is costly for shareholders, I find that if an investor<br />

were to go long firms with <strong>CEO</strong>s in the lowest age tercile <strong>and</strong> short firms in the highest age<br />

tercile, the investor would earn an annualized abnormal return <strong>of</strong> 6.0%.<br />

I also examine whether there are differences in the riskiness <strong>of</strong> the investments made by<br />

older versus younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. I find that older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest less in research <strong>and</strong> development,<br />

which tends to be a riskier form <strong>of</strong> investment. In addition, these <strong>CEO</strong>s have a greater propensity<br />

to make risk-reducing diversified acquisitions when they engage in takeovers <strong>and</strong> to run firms<br />

whose sales are more diversified across a greater number <strong>of</strong> operating segments. Put together,<br />

these findings are consistent with older <strong>CEO</strong>s preferring less risky investments. Further, given<br />

that diversification has been shown to be associated with reduced firm value (e.g., Berger <strong>and</strong><br />

Ofek (1995); Denis, Denis, <strong>and</strong> Sarin (1997); Denis, Denis, <strong>and</strong> Yost (2002)), these results<br />

2


suggest that the investment decisions made by older <strong>CEO</strong>s are not aligned with the interests <strong>of</strong><br />

shareholders.<br />

Next, I investigate whether the board <strong>of</strong> directors <strong>of</strong> firms that are managed by an older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> recognize the possibility <strong>of</strong> underinvestment problems <strong>and</strong> take steps to mitigate these<br />

problems using compensation incentives. Efficient contracting predicts that if the board<br />

recognizes the potential for underinvestment, then they will award the <strong>CEO</strong> with more equity-<br />

based performance sensitive compensation to mitigate underinvestment (e.g., Murphy (1986);<br />

Rajgopal <strong>and</strong> Shevlin (2002); Aggarwal <strong>and</strong> Samwick (2006)).<br />

For my sample <strong>of</strong> firms, I first verify whether a higher level <strong>of</strong> performance sensitive<br />

equity-based compensation is associated with greater firm-level investment. Specifically, I<br />

examine the relation between firm investment <strong>and</strong> the delta <strong>of</strong> a <strong>CEO</strong>’s annual stock option <strong>and</strong><br />

restricted stock grants, the dollar change in the <strong>CEO</strong>’s wealth resulting from these grants if the<br />

firm’s stock price increases by one percent. I find that for both older <strong>and</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s, a higher<br />

delta indeed leads to greater investment.<br />

Subsequently, I investigate whether the delta <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>’s annual stock option <strong>and</strong><br />

restricted stock grants differs between older <strong>and</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. Inconsistent with the efficient<br />

contracting prediction that firms provide <strong>CEO</strong>s with more equity-based performance sensitive<br />

compensation when the potential for underinvestment is greatest, I document that firms with<br />

older <strong>CEO</strong>s provide their <strong>CEO</strong>s with annual stock option <strong>and</strong> restricted stock grants that have a<br />

lower delta. Further, I find that older <strong>CEO</strong>s are provided with a higher annual cash salary,<br />

indicating that these <strong>CEO</strong>s do not receive less equity-based compensation because their overall<br />

pay level is lower, but instead, the lower level <strong>of</strong> equity-based compensation is the result <strong>of</strong> a<br />

substitution <strong>of</strong> performance-sensitive compensation for compensation that is not sensitive to<br />

3


performance for these <strong>CEO</strong>s. A potential explanation for why older <strong>CEO</strong>s receive less equity-<br />

based performance sensitive compensation <strong>and</strong> a greater annual cash salary than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

do is that older <strong>CEO</strong>s may have greater power <strong>and</strong> influence over the board. As such, these<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s could have the ability to award themselves with compensation that is less sensitive to firm<br />

performance. This would be consistent with managerial power theories that predict that since<br />

performance sensitive compensation ties more <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>'s wealth to the firm's performance,<br />

undiversified, risk-averse <strong>CEO</strong>s who have enough power over the board to influence the<br />

structure <strong>of</strong> their compensation will award themselves less performance sensitive compensation<br />

(e.g., Bebchuk, Fried, <strong>and</strong> Walker (2002); Bebchuk <strong>and</strong> Fried (2003); Cheng <strong>and</strong> Indjejikian<br />

(2009)).<br />

Overall, my paper makes several contributions. First, my study increases the<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the role <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> personal characteristics on corporate financial policies. Prior<br />

work has documented that <strong>CEO</strong> fixed effects explain a significant portion <strong>of</strong> the variation in<br />

corporate policies <strong>and</strong> accounting disclosure (Bertr<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Schoar (2003); Bamber, Jiang, <strong>and</strong><br />

Wang (2010)), <strong>CEO</strong>s have leverage preferences (Cronqvist, Makhija, <strong>and</strong> Yonker (2011)), <strong>CEO</strong><br />

confidence matters in financing decisions (Malmendier, Tate, <strong>and</strong> Yan (2011)), <strong>and</strong> <strong>CEO</strong><br />

behavioral traits help explain compensation structure (Graham, Harvey, <strong>and</strong> Puri (2010)). I<br />

provide evidence that the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong> is an important characteristic that can impact financial<br />

policy decisions. Specifically, I document that older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest less <strong>and</strong> make less risky<br />

investments than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> that this potentially leads to underinvestment <strong>and</strong> reduced<br />

performance in firms with large growth opportunities.<br />

In addition, I shed further light on how managerial power can result in <strong>CEO</strong>s influencing<br />

the structure <strong>of</strong> their own compensation, producing a greater divergence in the interests <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

4


<strong>and</strong> shareholders <strong>and</strong> imposing substantial costs on shareholders through foregone pr<strong>of</strong>itable<br />

investments (e.g., Bebchuk, Fried, <strong>and</strong> Walker (2002); Bebchuk <strong>and</strong> Fried (2003); Grinstein <strong>and</strong><br />

Hribar (2004); Garvey <strong>and</strong> Milbourn (2006); Cheng <strong>and</strong> Indjejikian (2009); Bebchuk, Cremers,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Peyer (2011)). My evidence suggests that, on average, the influence <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

potentially results in these individuals receiving a lower amount <strong>of</strong> equity-based performance<br />

sensitive compensation, <strong>and</strong> that this plays a part in the underinvestment problem <strong>and</strong> the<br />

underperformance <strong>of</strong> firms managed by an older <strong>CEO</strong>.<br />

I have organized the rest <strong>of</strong> the paper as follows. I provide an overview <strong>of</strong> previous<br />

empirical <strong>and</strong> theoretical research related to the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>and</strong> develop hypotheses <strong>and</strong><br />

related empirical predictions in section 2. In section 3, I present the sample selection process <strong>and</strong><br />

summary statistics. In section 4, I report the empirical findings. Lastly, in section 5, I conclude<br />

the paper.<br />

2. Related literature, hypothesis development, <strong>and</strong> empirical predictions<br />

2.1 <strong>CEO</strong> age <strong>and</strong> investment activity<br />

Prior theoretical work provides two competing views about how executives’ age could<br />

influence their investment decisions. First, Holmstrom (1999) <strong>and</strong> Scharfstein <strong>and</strong> Stein (1990)<br />

develop market learning models, which lead to the prediction that younger <strong>CEO</strong>s are more risk-<br />

averse <strong>and</strong> therefore, invest less aggressively than older <strong>CEO</strong>s. Specifically, these papers argue<br />

that because younger <strong>CEO</strong>s do not have a previous record <strong>of</strong> accomplishments as <strong>CEO</strong>, they may<br />

face greater labor market scrutiny if they make a bad investment decision, which may<br />

significantly reduce future career opportunities. As a result, younger <strong>CEO</strong>s are reluctant to<br />

pursue an aggressive investment strategy.<br />

5


Second, Prendergast <strong>and</strong> Stole (1996) develop a managerial signaling model, which leads<br />

to the prediction that younger <strong>CEO</strong>s make more <strong>and</strong> bolder investments compared to their older<br />

counterparts. Prendergast <strong>and</strong> Stole (1996) argue that in an effort to signal to the market that they<br />

are <strong>of</strong> superior ability, younger <strong>CEO</strong>s pursue a more aggressive investment style. Further, older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s are reluctant to change investment behavior, as this may indicate that their previous<br />

investment decisions were incorrect. Consequently, younger <strong>CEO</strong>s pursue a more aggressive<br />

investment style compared to the investment style <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s. 1<br />

In addition to these two models, it is possible that there are <strong>CEO</strong> characteristics beyond<br />

risk-aversion <strong>and</strong> career concerns that result in older <strong>CEO</strong>s investing at a level below that <strong>of</strong><br />

younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. Notably, prior work suggests that entrenched <strong>CEO</strong>s make less risky investments<br />

<strong>and</strong> also invest less, preferring a quiet life (e.g., Amihud <strong>and</strong> Lev (1981), Shleifer <strong>and</strong> Vishny<br />

(1989), <strong>and</strong> Gompers, Ishii, <strong>and</strong> Metrick (2003), Bertr<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Mullainathan (2003)). If older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s are more likely to have greater influence within the firm, they could get away with<br />

pursuing a quiet life, resulting in lower investment levels relative to their younger counterparts. 2<br />

There are two contemporaneous papers that also empirically examine the relation<br />

between <strong>CEO</strong> age <strong>and</strong> firm-level investment. Yim (2010) provides evidence that younger <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

are more likely to make acquisitions. She argues that because there are permanent increases in<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> compensation following an acquisition, this incentivizes younger <strong>CEO</strong>s to make more<br />

1 The prediction made by managerial signaling models is related to the horizon problem where older <strong>CEO</strong>s near<br />

retirement will sacrifice investment in long-term projects that are good for the firm's long-term performance in<br />

exchange for short-term projects that temporarily boost short-term performance (e.g., Smith <strong>and</strong> Watts (1982);<br />

Dechow <strong>and</strong> Sloan (1991); Cheng (2004); Antia, Pantzalis, <strong>and</strong> Park (2010)). However, the horizon problem only<br />

addresses whether <strong>CEO</strong>s in their final years <strong>of</strong> tenure reduce investment. It does not address whether the level or<br />

riskiness <strong>of</strong> investments differs between older <strong>and</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

2 Other studies documenting potential reasons why the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong> could affect investment behavior include<br />

Levi, Li, <strong>and</strong> Zhang (2010) who report that younger <strong>CEO</strong>s are more aggressive during mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions <strong>and</strong><br />

attribute their findings to younger <strong>CEO</strong>s having higher levels <strong>of</strong> testosterone. Roberts <strong>and</strong> Rosenberg (2006) voice<br />

concerns <strong>of</strong> reduced energy levels in the elderly, <strong>and</strong> Taylor (1975) finds that younger managers are more confident<br />

in their decisions.<br />

6


acquisitions earlier in their careers. Li, Low, <strong>and</strong> Makhija (2011) examine the differences in<br />

investment behavior between older <strong>and</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s by examining plant-level investment<br />

decisions <strong>and</strong> show that older <strong>CEO</strong>s have a less aggressive investment style compared to<br />

younger <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

2.2 The relation between investment activity <strong>and</strong> performance sensitive compensation<br />

Several theoretical studies predict that linking <strong>CEO</strong> compensation to performance can<br />

lead to <strong>CEO</strong>s making optimal investment decisions. Some <strong>of</strong> these studies include Lambert<br />

(1986) in the context <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong>s dismissing positive net present value projects due to perceived<br />

risks, Campbell, Chan, <strong>and</strong> Marino (1989) in the context <strong>of</strong> information asymmetry about <strong>CEO</strong><br />

ability <strong>and</strong> project value, Smith <strong>and</strong> Watts (1982) in the context <strong>of</strong> growth opportunities,<br />

Hirshleifer <strong>and</strong> Suh (1992) in the context <strong>of</strong> risk-aversion, risky projects, <strong>and</strong> monitoring, <strong>and</strong><br />

Bizjak, Brickley, <strong>and</strong> Coles (1993) in the context <strong>of</strong> asymmetric information <strong>and</strong> stock price<br />

manipulation. In addition, Aggarwal <strong>and</strong> Samwick (2006) show that investment activity is<br />

increasing in the use <strong>of</strong> performance sensitive compensation.<br />

Empirically, Smith <strong>and</strong> Watts (1982), Gaver <strong>and</strong> Gaver (1993), <strong>and</strong> Baber, Janakiraman,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Kang (1996) report that firms with more investment opportunities compensate <strong>CEO</strong>s with<br />

more performance sensitive compensation. Guay (1999) finds that when firms have more<br />

investment opportunities, <strong>CEO</strong>s will not only have more performance sensitive compensation,<br />

but they will also have more compensation that is sensitive to equity risk. Consistent with this,<br />

Ryan <strong>and</strong> Wiggins (2001), Rajgopal <strong>and</strong> Shevlin (2002), <strong>and</strong> Coles, Daniel, <strong>and</strong> Naveen (2006)<br />

document that <strong>CEO</strong>s whose wealth is more sensitive to stock returns <strong>and</strong> stock return volatility<br />

make more risky investments. Moreover, Barker <strong>and</strong> Mueller (2002) show that R&D spending is<br />

7


greater in firms whose <strong>CEO</strong> has more wealth invested in the firm, <strong>and</strong> Datta, Isk<strong>and</strong>ar-Datta, <strong>and</strong><br />

Raman (2001) report that <strong>CEO</strong>s with more equity-based compensation make better acquisition<br />

decisions. Lastly, Cheng (2004) finds that <strong>CEO</strong>s with greater option compensation are less likely<br />

to cut long-term R&D expenditures in their final years in <strong>of</strong>fice as a means to inflate short-term<br />

earnings.<br />

In addition to work directly examining the relation between <strong>CEO</strong> age <strong>and</strong> compensation<br />

policies, there are studies that examine the relation between <strong>CEO</strong> tenure <strong>and</strong> compensation<br />

policies. Cremers <strong>and</strong> Palia (2010) document that there is a positive relation between <strong>CEO</strong> tenure<br />

<strong>and</strong> both pay level <strong>and</strong> pay-performance sensitivity, which is consistent with a career concerns<br />

hypothesis that <strong>CEO</strong>s in the later stages <strong>of</strong> their careers require more explicit incentives to<br />

replace implicit labor market incentives. However, Zheng (2010) shows that equity-based<br />

compensation increases during the early years <strong>of</strong> tenure for outside <strong>CEO</strong>s, supporting a learning<br />

hypothesis that says boards use equity-based compensation as a tool to learn about the <strong>CEO</strong>’s<br />

abilities. 3<br />

3 These results in Cremers <strong>and</strong> Palia (2010) <strong>and</strong> Zheng (2010) differ primarily due to the different definitions <strong>of</strong><br />

equity incentives that the authors use to construct a measure <strong>of</strong> equity-based pay-performance sensitivity. In the first<br />

study, the authors use new equity awards <strong>and</strong> all outst<strong>and</strong>ing equity awards to calculate the <strong>CEO</strong>’s equity-based payperformance<br />

sensitivity, whereas in the latter study, the author only uses new equity awards. In the first study, the<br />

positive relation between tenure <strong>and</strong> equity-based pay-performance sensitivity could be driven by the accumulation<br />

<strong>of</strong> outst<strong>and</strong>ing awards over time. This approach would be appropriate if the researcher wants to capture the <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

total equity incentives. However, similar to the latter study, I am interested in how firms manage <strong>CEO</strong> equity<br />

incentives to incentivize the <strong>CEO</strong> to make optimal investment decisions. Since Core <strong>and</strong> Guay (1999) show that<br />

firms will use annual equity grants to manage the level <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> equity incentives when incentives deviate from the<br />

optimal level, only using new equity grants to calculate equity-based pay-performance sensitivity is most<br />

appropriate for my study.<br />

8


2.3 Hypotheses <strong>and</strong> empirical predictions<br />

The discussion in the prior sections about the effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> age on a firm’s investment<br />

level leads to two competing hypotheses.<br />

Hypothesis 1: The aggressiveness <strong>of</strong> a <strong>CEO</strong>’s investment behavior is increasing in his<br />

age.<br />

Hypothesis 2: The aggressiveness <strong>of</strong> a <strong>CEO</strong>’s investment behavior is decreasing in<br />

his age.<br />

These hypotheses generate the empirical prediction that the level <strong>of</strong> firm investment is positively<br />

(negatively) associated with the <strong>CEO</strong>’s age.<br />

In firms with important growth opportunities, the extent to which a <strong>CEO</strong> has an<br />

aggressive investment style has a larger effect on his firm’s investment practices, given that<br />

when a firm has an abundance <strong>of</strong> investment opportunities, it is easier for a <strong>CEO</strong> with an<br />

aggressive investment style to invest heavily. Consequently, if the age <strong>of</strong> a <strong>CEO</strong> has a positive<br />

effect on the amount <strong>of</strong> investment he undertakes <strong>and</strong> this is driven by younger <strong>CEO</strong>s having a<br />

higher level <strong>of</strong> risk aversion, then in firms with large growth opportunities older <strong>CEO</strong>s should<br />

invest even more relative to younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. Likewise, if a <strong>CEO</strong>’s age has a negative effect on his<br />

investment activity <strong>and</strong> this occurs because younger <strong>CEO</strong>s make more <strong>and</strong> bolder investments to<br />

signal their ability or due to older <strong>CEO</strong>s preferring a quiet life, then in firms with larger<br />

investment opportunity sets, the finding that older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest less should be more pronounced.<br />

Thus, the study’s two main hypotheses also lead to the empirical prediction that the effect <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>CEO</strong> age on a firm’s investment level is more pronounced in firms with higher growth<br />

opportunities.<br />

9


In addition, since firm diversification reduces firm-specific risk (e.g., Mansi <strong>and</strong> Reeb<br />

(2002); Duchin (2010)), the age cohort with the smaller risk tolerance <strong>and</strong> lower propensity to<br />

invest aggressively will prefer that the firm have a more diversified asset base. Thus, Hypotheses<br />

1 <strong>and</strong> 2 also predict that younger (older) <strong>CEO</strong>s are more likely to make diversifying acquisitions<br />

when they do make acquisitions <strong>and</strong> more likely to have business operations in more operating<br />

segments.<br />

Different forms <strong>of</strong> investment are associated with varying levels <strong>of</strong> risk. R&D<br />

expenditures are a riskier form <strong>of</strong> investment than are capital expenditures due to their higher<br />

degree <strong>of</strong> uncertainty regarding future benefits (e.g., Kothari, Laguerre, <strong>and</strong> Leone (2002); Coles,<br />

Daniel, <strong>and</strong> Naveen (2006); Cassell, Huang, Sanchez, <strong>and</strong> Stuart (2012)). Consequently,<br />

Hypotheses 1 <strong>and</strong> 2 also predict that younger (older) <strong>CEO</strong>s prefer to invest in less R&D intensive<br />

projects.<br />

Efficient contracting predicts that firms use equity-based performance sensitive<br />

compensation as a tool to align the incentives <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong>s with those <strong>of</strong> shareholders <strong>and</strong> mitigate<br />

the potential for underinvestment. This leads to the study’s third hypothesis.<br />

Hypothesis 3: If either younger or older <strong>CEO</strong>s underinvest, then firms try to mitigate this<br />

problem by providing the underinvesting group <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong>s with additional<br />

equity-based performance sensitive compensation.<br />

The hypothesis results in the prediction that if younger (older) <strong>CEO</strong>s underinvest then there will<br />

be a positive relation between the amount <strong>of</strong> equity-based performance sensitive compensation<br />

that the <strong>CEO</strong> receives <strong>and</strong> whether he is a younger (older) versus an older (younger) <strong>CEO</strong>.<br />

10


3. Sample description <strong>and</strong> variable construction<br />

3.1 Sample selection<br />

I begin my sample selection process by identifying all <strong>CEO</strong>s on Execucomp <strong>of</strong> firms with<br />

fiscal year-ends between 1993 <strong>and</strong> 2010. I use Execucomp to collect data on <strong>CEO</strong> age, tenure,<br />

<strong>and</strong> compensation measures. I discard observations if the <strong>CEO</strong> owns more than 10% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

shares outst<strong>and</strong>ing because incentive compensation for <strong>and</strong> the investment decisions <strong>of</strong> these<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s are unlikely to be similar to those <strong>of</strong> other <strong>CEO</strong>s with less stock ownership. 4 Moreover, I<br />

eliminate <strong>CEO</strong>-year observations in which the <strong>CEO</strong> only serves a partial year. I exclude utilities<br />

(SIC 4900-4999), financials (SIC 6000-6999), <strong>and</strong> quasi-public firms (SIC codes greater than<br />

9900). I collect accounting variables from Compustat, return data from CRSP, <strong>and</strong> data on M&A<br />

transactions from Thomson’s SDC Spectrum Mergers <strong>and</strong> Acquisitions database. After merging<br />

the databases <strong>and</strong> deleting observations with missing values <strong>of</strong> variables needed for the main<br />

regressions, the sample has 13,769 <strong>CEO</strong>-year observations.<br />

3.2 Measuring investment activity <strong>and</strong> investment opportunities<br />

The primary variables <strong>of</strong> interest include the firm's investment activity, the firm's<br />

investment opportunity set, the <strong>CEO</strong>'s age, <strong>and</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>'s equity-based performance sensitive<br />

compensation. To measure the firm's investment activity, I calculate investment as the sum <strong>of</strong><br />

capital expenditures <strong>and</strong> R&D expenditures divided by total assets at the beginning <strong>of</strong> the year. 5<br />

To proxy for the firm's investment opportunity set, I use two different industry proxies.<br />

Using industry proxies for growth opportunities instead <strong>of</strong> firm-level measures mitigates the<br />

4<br />

As a robustness check, I rerun all my tests excluding the restriction that <strong>CEO</strong>s own less than 10% <strong>of</strong> the firm. All<br />

<strong>of</strong> my results continue to hold.<br />

5<br />

As a robustness check, I also calculate investment activity as the sum <strong>of</strong> the firm's capital expenditures, R&D<br />

expenses, acquisition related expenses, <strong>and</strong> advertising expenses divided by total assets at the beginning <strong>of</strong> the year<br />

(Faulkender <strong>and</strong> Petersen (2010)). The results are robust to using this alternative.<br />

11


potential problem that a firm’s current investment opportunity set is a function <strong>of</strong> the firm’s<br />

investment decisions. For the first measure, I calculate each industry’s market-to-book ratio as<br />

the median <strong>of</strong> each firm’s market-to-book ratio in each industry every year. I define industries at<br />

the three-digit SIC level. I calculate a firm’s market-to-book ratio as the book value <strong>of</strong> assets<br />

plus the market value <strong>of</strong> equity less the book value <strong>of</strong> equity less balance sheet deferred taxes<br />

divided by the total book value <strong>of</strong> assets. I calculate the book value <strong>of</strong> equity as the book value <strong>of</strong><br />

shareholder equity less the value <strong>of</strong> preferred stock.<br />

For the second measure, I calculate each industry’s factor score as the median <strong>of</strong> each<br />

firm’s factor score in each industry every year. I define industries at the three-digit SIC level.<br />

Following Baber, Janakiraman, <strong>and</strong> Kang (1996) <strong>and</strong> Guay (1999), I create a growth factor<br />

score to proxy for the firm’s investment opportunity set by creating one variable from combining<br />

the firm’s three-year average investment intensity, the firm’s three-year annual growth rate in<br />

market value <strong>of</strong> assets, the firm’s market-to-book ratio, <strong>and</strong> the firm’s R&D expenditures. 6<br />

To analyze how the influence <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> age on investment activity varies with the firm's<br />

investment opportunity set, each year, I partition firms into two groups based on whether the<br />

firm has above or below median investment opportunities in that year based on the proxy used. I<br />

then create indicator variables that equal one if the firm is in the group with the highest<br />

investment opportunities <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise.<br />

3.3 <strong>CEO</strong> age proxies <strong>and</strong> equity-based performance sensitive compensation<br />

Next, I obtain the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong> from Execucomp <strong>and</strong> create a discrete <strong>and</strong> continuous<br />

measure for <strong>CEO</strong> age. By creating two variables that capture the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>, I want to show<br />

6 For more details regarding the methodology for creating the growth factor score <strong>and</strong> specific variable definitions,<br />

see Baber, Janakiraman, <strong>and</strong> Kang (1996).<br />

12


that the results are robust to the measure used to capture <strong>CEO</strong> age, <strong>and</strong> that the variable<br />

definition is not driving the results. For the first measure, each year, I rank <strong>CEO</strong>s into terciles<br />

based on the <strong>CEO</strong>'s age. I then create an indicator variable, Older <strong>CEO</strong>, that is equal to one if the<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>’s age falls into the top age tercile <strong>and</strong> that is equal to zero if the <strong>CEO</strong>’s age falls into the<br />

bottom two age terciles. Due to ease <strong>of</strong> interpretation, I base most <strong>of</strong> my discussion on this<br />

measure. For the second measure, I simply use the <strong>CEO</strong>'s age in the given year.<br />

To measure equity-based pay-performance sensitivity, I follow the method outlined in<br />

Core <strong>and</strong> Guay (2002) to calculate the <strong>CEO</strong>'s delta <strong>of</strong> new option <strong>and</strong> stock awards. Delta is the<br />

dollar change in the <strong>CEO</strong>'s option <strong>and</strong> stock grant for a 1% change in the firm's stock price.<br />

Following their method, I calculate stock option values <strong>and</strong> their sensitivity to stock price based<br />

on the Black-Scholes formula adjusted for dividend payouts (Black <strong>and</strong> Scholes (1973); Merton<br />

(1973)).<br />

Table I presents summary statistics <strong>of</strong> the data. The mean level <strong>of</strong> investment is 10.6%.<br />

The average <strong>CEO</strong> is 55 years old <strong>and</strong> has been <strong>CEO</strong> for 6.8 years. Since I am analyzing<br />

Execucomp firms, which correspond to S&P 1500 firms, the firm characteristics are reflective <strong>of</strong><br />

larger, more pr<strong>of</strong>itable firms.<br />

4. Empirical results<br />

4.1 Univariate results<br />

Table II compares <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>and</strong> firm characteristics between older <strong>and</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. I<br />

classify a <strong>CEO</strong> as older if his age is in the top tercile in a given year, whereas I classify a <strong>CEO</strong> as<br />

younger if his age is in the bottom two terciles in a given year. This table shows that both firm<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> characteristics differ significantly between the subsamples based on whether a <strong>CEO</strong> is<br />

13


older or younger. Thus, controlling for firm <strong>and</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> characteristics in multivariate regressions<br />

is important. Table II also documents univariate results suggesting that older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest less<br />

<strong>and</strong> receive less equity compensation than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

An older <strong>CEO</strong> is on average 62.5 years old with tenure <strong>of</strong> 9.6 years, whereas a younger<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> is on average 51.3 years old with tenure <strong>of</strong> 5.6 years. Moreover, 13% <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s are<br />

classified as founders <strong>of</strong> the firm, while only 10% <strong>of</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s are classified as founders. In<br />

addition, older <strong>CEO</strong>s manage larger, more mature, more levered, <strong>and</strong> less pr<strong>of</strong>itable firms, with<br />

slightly lower growth opportunities. Since older <strong>CEO</strong>s manage larger firms, this partially<br />

explains why older <strong>CEO</strong>s receive more compensation, as older <strong>CEO</strong>s receive larger annual<br />

salaries, receive more total compensation, <strong>and</strong> have higher portfolio Deltas.<br />

4.2 Multivariate results<br />

In this section, I test Hypotheses 1 <strong>and</strong> 2 that the aggressiveness <strong>of</strong> a <strong>CEO</strong>’s investment<br />

behavior is increasing (decreasing) in his age. I first report regressions <strong>of</strong> investment activity on<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> age <strong>and</strong> investment opportunities to analyze differences in investment behavior between<br />

older <strong>and</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. I then investigate the nature <strong>of</strong> the investments made by older <strong>and</strong><br />

younger <strong>CEO</strong>s <strong>and</strong> whether differences in investment activity translate into differences in firm<br />

performance. Lastly, I test efficient contracting predictions <strong>and</strong> document whether firms<br />

compensate older <strong>CEO</strong>s in a manner that is consistent with firms attempting to mitigate potential<br />

underinvestment problems.<br />

In all regressions, I measure the dependent variable at time t, while I measure the<br />

independent variables at time t-1 to reduce the possibility <strong>of</strong> reverse causality. Since investment<br />

activity <strong>and</strong> the average level <strong>of</strong> awarded equity-based performance sensitive compensation is<br />

14


likely to vary by year <strong>and</strong> industry, in all regressions, I include year <strong>and</strong> industry fixed effects in<br />

my models. Moreover, all t-statistics are calculated using st<strong>and</strong>ard errors clustered at the firm<br />

level.<br />

4.2.1 The relation between <strong>CEO</strong> age, investment opportunities, <strong>and</strong> investment activity<br />

To test Hypotheses 1 <strong>and</strong> 2 that investment behavior becomes more or less aggressive as<br />

the <strong>CEO</strong> ages, I examine the difference in investment activity between older <strong>and</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

Panel A <strong>of</strong> Table III provides the regression results <strong>of</strong> firm-level investment activity on <strong>CEO</strong> age<br />

<strong>and</strong> other control variables. The dependent variable in all six models is the sum <strong>of</strong> R&D<br />

expenditures <strong>and</strong> capital expenditures divided by the firm’s book value <strong>of</strong> assets.<br />

I control for <strong>CEO</strong> tenure because it is correlated with <strong>CEO</strong> age (0.32), <strong>and</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> tenure is<br />

likely to also impact the investments made by a <strong>CEO</strong>. Thus, by controlling for <strong>CEO</strong> tenure, I<br />

isolate the effect that is unique to <strong>CEO</strong> age. I also include the delta <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>’s portfolio, which<br />

measures the change in <strong>CEO</strong> wealth given a 1% change in their firm’s stock price. Following<br />

Faulkender <strong>and</strong> Petersen (2010), I control for firm size, as measured by the firm’s market value<br />

<strong>of</strong> assets, the firm’s market-to-book ratio, <strong>and</strong> the firm's pre-investment pr<strong>of</strong>its scaled by book<br />

value <strong>of</strong> assets. I calculate the firm's pre-investment pr<strong>of</strong>its as the sum <strong>of</strong> earnings before<br />

interest, taxes, depreciation, <strong>and</strong> amortization (EBITDA), R&D expenses, <strong>and</strong> advertising<br />

expenses. Moreover, I include an indicator variable that is equal to one if a firm is in an industry<br />

with above median growth opportunities, as proxied by median industry market-to-book <strong>and</strong><br />

median industry growth factor score (Baber, Janakiraman, <strong>and</strong> Kang (1996)).<br />

In addition to the variables used by Faulkender <strong>and</strong> Petersen (2010), I also include the<br />

firm's market leverage <strong>and</strong> the firm's three-year average dividend yield. Since a firm’s<br />

15


investment activity depends on available capital <strong>and</strong> since Yermack (1995) <strong>and</strong> Dechow, Hutton,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Sloan (1996) hypothesize that liquidity constrained firms may compensate <strong>CEO</strong>s with stock<br />

options rather than cash compensation, I include the firm's cash holdings in all regressions. I also<br />

include firm age <strong>and</strong> whether the <strong>CEO</strong> is a founder. To determine if the <strong>CEO</strong> is a founder, I<br />

follow the process outlined in Bebchuk, Cremers, <strong>and</strong> Peyer (2011) <strong>and</strong> define a <strong>CEO</strong> as a<br />

founder if the <strong>CEO</strong> was <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm when the firm first began trading. 7<br />

The results from Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 2 show that older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

do. This result is consistent with Hypothesis 2 that predicts that the aggressiveness <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong>s’<br />

investment behavior is decreasing in <strong>CEO</strong> age. The coefficient estimates from Model 1 imply<br />

that an older <strong>CEO</strong> invests 0.46 percentage points below the investment level <strong>of</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

Since the average investment level <strong>of</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s is 11.14%, older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest 4.13% less<br />

than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s do.<br />

In Models 3-6, I interact proxies for <strong>CEO</strong> age <strong>and</strong> proxies for whether a firm has high<br />

growth opportunities to determine whether the underinvestment <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s is a potential<br />

source <strong>of</strong> agency costs. To classify firms as those with high growth opportunities, in Models 3<br />

<strong>and</strong> 4, I create an indicator variable that is equal to one if the firm is in an industry with an above<br />

median market-to-book ratio. In Models 5 <strong>and</strong> 6, I create an indicator variable that is equal to<br />

one if a firm is in an industry with an above median industry growth factor score. Models 3-6<br />

indicate that it is only in firms with above median growth opportunities that older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest<br />

less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. 8 The coefficient estimates from Model 3 imply that an older <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> a<br />

7 All variables are winsorized at the 1% <strong>and</strong> 99% levels <strong>and</strong> adjusted to 2009 dollar values. However, variables that<br />

are naturally censored at zero are only winsorized at the 99% level.<br />

8 Since firms with above median growth opportunities have higher investment levels compared to firms with below<br />

median growth opportunities (13.32% vs. 7.96%), the result that older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s do only<br />

in high growth firms could be a mechanical relation. To check if this is the case, I partition the sample into firms<br />

with above median investment opportunities <strong>and</strong> those with below median investment opportunities <strong>and</strong> run separate<br />

16


high growth firm invests 0.90 (=0.09 + 0.81) percentage points, which is equivalent to 6.44%,<br />

less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s managing similar firms. Since investment should typically have a larger<br />

impact on firm value in high growth firms, this underinvestment is a potential source <strong>of</strong><br />

shareholder value destruction.<br />

Consistent with other studies, I document that firms that are more pr<strong>of</strong>itable <strong>and</strong> firms<br />

with higher cash holdings have higher levels <strong>of</strong> investment. In addition, firms that pay higher<br />

dividends invest less. A percentage point increase in the firm's dividend yield, results in a 0.67<br />

percentage point decrease in investment. This is equivalent to a 6.32% decrease from the mean<br />

investment level.<br />

In Panel B <strong>of</strong> Table III, I provide some insights on whether <strong>CEO</strong> power might in part<br />

drive the results in Panel A. If older <strong>CEO</strong>s prefer a quiet life <strong>and</strong> want to pursue a less aggressive<br />

investment style, then older <strong>CEO</strong>s with power over the board might invest less so that they can<br />

pursue the quiet life (Bertr<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Mullainathan (2003)). Older <strong>CEO</strong>s who also have long tenure<br />

at their firm may be more likely to have power <strong>and</strong> influence over the board. In Panel B <strong>of</strong> Table<br />

III, I examine whether the results in Panel A may in part be driven by <strong>CEO</strong> power by interacting<br />

the two proxies <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> age with the mean-adjusted logarithm <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> tenure. Since older <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

only invest less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s in firms with above median investment opportunities, in<br />

Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, I limit the sample to those firms with above median industry market-to-book<br />

ratios, <strong>and</strong> in Models 3 <strong>and</strong> 4, I restrict the sample to those firms with above median industry<br />

factor scores. The dependent variable in all four models is the sum <strong>of</strong> R&D expenditures <strong>and</strong><br />

capital expenditures divided by the firm’s book value <strong>of</strong> assets.<br />

regressions. The results continue to indicate that older <strong>CEO</strong>s only significantly invest less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s do in<br />

high growth firms.<br />

17


The results in Models 1-4 show that the negative relation between <strong>CEO</strong> age <strong>and</strong><br />

investment is more pronounced when <strong>CEO</strong>s have longer tenure. In fact, the coefficient estimates<br />

from Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 3 imply that older <strong>CEO</strong>s only invest less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s do when they<br />

have longer tenures. Overall, the results suggest that when older <strong>CEO</strong>s have greater power due to<br />

being with a firm longer, they use their influence to pursue a less aggressive investment style <strong>and</strong><br />

the quiet life. In addition, since older <strong>CEO</strong>s have almost twice the tenure length as younger<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s, this further supports the notion that there exists an underinvestment problem <strong>and</strong> agency<br />

costs associated with older <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

To further investigate how <strong>CEO</strong> age affects the aggressiveness <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>’s investment<br />

behavior, in Panels C <strong>and</strong> D <strong>of</strong> Table III, I decompose investment into R&D expenditures <strong>and</strong><br />

capital expenditures <strong>and</strong> rerun the regressions from Panel A. In Panel C, the dependent variable<br />

is R&D expenditures divided by total assets, <strong>and</strong> in Panel D, the dependent variable is capital<br />

expenditures divided by total assets. The results <strong>of</strong> the two panels show that the lower investment<br />

level <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s is driven by older <strong>CEO</strong>s making fewer investments in R&D. The coefficient<br />

estimates from Model 3 <strong>of</strong> Panel C imply that in high growth firms, an older <strong>CEO</strong> invests 0.63<br />

percentage points less in R&D than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s do. The average investment in R&D by<br />

younger <strong>CEO</strong>s is 7.55%, which implies older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest 8.34% less in R&D than younger<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s do. Since R&D is generally considered a more risky form <strong>of</strong> investment (e.g., Kothari,<br />

Laguerre, <strong>and</strong> Leone (2002); Coles, Daniel, <strong>and</strong> Naveen (2006); Cassell, Huang, Sanchez, <strong>and</strong><br />

Stuart (2012)) <strong>and</strong> investment in R&D is a large component <strong>of</strong> value in high growth firms, this<br />

finding further supports the hypothesis that the aggressiveness <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong>s’ investment behavior is<br />

decreasing in his age <strong>and</strong> costly to shareholders.<br />

18


An alternative explanation for the Table III results is that there is a matching process<br />

between firms <strong>and</strong> <strong>CEO</strong>s, where older <strong>CEO</strong>s choose to work for firms with lower investments<br />

rates or firms with lower investment rates choose to hire older <strong>CEO</strong>s. To further test the<br />

hypothesis that older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s due to traits that are specifically tied<br />

to the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>, in Table IV, I examine investment activity around <strong>CEO</strong> turnover. If older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s truly drive lower investment rates, then when an older <strong>CEO</strong> replaces a younger <strong>CEO</strong>,<br />

firm-level investment should significantly decline. I use two proxies to capture the difference in<br />

ages between the newly hired <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>and</strong> the recently departed <strong>CEO</strong>. The first proxy is simply the<br />

age <strong>of</strong> the hired <strong>CEO</strong> less the age <strong>of</strong> the departing <strong>CEO</strong>. I call this variable the <strong>Age</strong> Difference.<br />

For the second proxy, I rank <strong>Age</strong> Difference into terciles, where the highest tercile represents<br />

turnovers where the new <strong>CEO</strong> is older than the replaced <strong>CEO</strong>. I then create indicator variables<br />

for the second <strong>and</strong> third terciles <strong>and</strong> call these variable Medium <strong>Age</strong> Difference <strong>and</strong> Largest <strong>Age</strong><br />

Difference, respectively.<br />

Table IV provides further evidence that older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. In<br />

Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, I measure the change in investment as the investment rate in the year after the<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> was hired less the investment rate one year before the <strong>CEO</strong> was hired. In Models 3 <strong>and</strong> 4, I<br />

measure the change in investment as the two-year average investment rate over the two years<br />

after the <strong>CEO</strong> was hired less the two-year average investment rate over the two years before the<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> was hired. All models indicate that when older <strong>CEO</strong>s replace younger <strong>CEO</strong>s, firm-level<br />

investment activity decreases substantially. For example, if there is a two st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation<br />

increase in <strong>Age</strong> Difference (2*9.8), then the coefficient estimates from Model 1 imply that a 60<br />

year-old <strong>CEO</strong> replacing a 40 year-old <strong>CEO</strong> is expected to cut investment by 0.98 percentage<br />

points. Since the mean investment rate in the year preceding the turnover is 10.8%, this translates<br />

19


into a 9.1% cut in investment. Using the change in the two-year average investment rate, the<br />

coefficient estimates from Model 3 imply that a two st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation increase in <strong>Age</strong><br />

Difference translates into a reduction in investment <strong>of</strong> 11.3%. Overall, the results suggest that<br />

when an older (younger) <strong>CEO</strong> replaces a younger (older) <strong>CEO</strong>, the new <strong>CEO</strong> decreases<br />

(increases) investments.<br />

4.2.2 The relation between <strong>CEO</strong> age <strong>and</strong> the nature <strong>of</strong> investments<br />

Tables III <strong>and</strong> IV document that older <strong>CEO</strong>s invest significantly less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

do in firms with the above median investment opportunities, suggesting that the investment<br />

behavior <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s may conflict with the interests <strong>of</strong> shareholders. In this section, I examine<br />

the nature <strong>of</strong> the investments made by older <strong>and</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s to see if the effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> age<br />

on investment behavior extends beyond the <strong>CEO</strong>’s choice <strong>of</strong> investment level. An observable<br />

investment choice is whether the <strong>CEO</strong> diversifies the firm’s asset base. Since diversification has<br />

been shown to reduce firm value (e.g., Berger <strong>and</strong> Ofek (1995); Denis, Denis, <strong>and</strong> Sarin (1997);<br />

Denis, Denis, <strong>and</strong> Yost (2002)), if older <strong>CEO</strong>s are more likely to diversify the firm, this would<br />

provide further evidence that greater age is likely to create agency costs between managers <strong>and</strong><br />

shareholders.<br />

I only study firms with above median investment opportunities, as it is in these firms that<br />

the underinvestment problem exists. In Table V, I present the second stage results from a<br />

Heckman Two-Step selection model. In the first stage, I model the choice <strong>of</strong> whether the firm<br />

makes an acquisition in a given year. 9 Given a firm makes an acquisition in a given year, in the<br />

second stage, I model whether the acquisition is a diversifying acquisition. A diversifying<br />

acquisition occurs when the target firm is not in the same two-digit SIC industry as the acquirer.<br />

9 First stage results are in Table I <strong>of</strong> Appendix A.<br />

20


The sample selection process <strong>and</strong> the selection <strong>of</strong> control variables are influenced by Masulis,<br />

Wang, <strong>and</strong> Xie (2007). To enter the acquisition sample, the acquisition must be completed, <strong>and</strong><br />

the acquirer must control less than 50% <strong>of</strong> the target prior to the acquisition announcement <strong>and</strong><br />

own 100% <strong>of</strong> the target after the acquisition is completed. In addition, the deal value must be<br />

greater than $1 million <strong>and</strong> at least 1% <strong>of</strong> the acquirer’s market value <strong>of</strong> equity measured on the<br />

11 th trading day prior to the acquisition announcement.<br />

In Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, I limit the sample to those firms with above median industry market-<br />

to-book ratios, <strong>and</strong> in Models 3 <strong>and</strong> 4, I restrict the sample to those firms with above median<br />

industry factor scores. The coefficient estimates represent marginal effects. Overall, the results<br />

indicate that older <strong>CEO</strong>s are more likely to make diversifying acquisitions compared to younger<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s. The coefficient estimates from Model 1 imply that older <strong>CEO</strong>s are 6.8% more likely to<br />

acquire a firm that does not share the same two-digit SIC industry as their firm. Thus, the Table<br />

V findings suggest that when older <strong>CEO</strong>s make investments, they are more likely to make<br />

investments in an effort to reduce the firm’s overall risk.<br />

As an additional test, I examine the relation between the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>and</strong> firm-level<br />

diversification. I collect business segment data from the Compustat Industrial Segments Tapes.<br />

To capture firm level diversification, I count the number <strong>of</strong> different business segments that the<br />

firm operates in, <strong>and</strong> I create a Herfindahl Index that captures revenue concentration across<br />

segments. I define the Herfindahl Index as the sum <strong>of</strong> the square <strong>of</strong> segment sales divided by the<br />

square <strong>of</strong> firm sales.<br />

Table VI reports the results <strong>of</strong> Tobit regressions <strong>of</strong> firm-level diversification on <strong>CEO</strong> age<br />

in firms with the greatest investment opportunities. In Models 1-4, I limit the sample to those<br />

firms with above median industry market-to-book ratios, <strong>and</strong> in Models 5-8, I restrict the sample<br />

21


to those firms with above median industry factor scores. The dependent variable in Models 1, 2,<br />

5, <strong>and</strong> 6 is the number <strong>of</strong> operating segments that the firm operates in, <strong>and</strong> in Models 3, 4, 7, <strong>and</strong><br />

8 the dependent variable is the Herfindahl Index. The coefficient estimates represent marginal<br />

effects. The results show that older <strong>CEO</strong>s manage more diversified firms, as captured by a<br />

greater number <strong>of</strong> operating segments <strong>and</strong> a lower Herfindahl Index. For example, the coefficient<br />

estimates from Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 3 indicate that older <strong>CEO</strong>s manage firms with 0.20 more business<br />

segments <strong>and</strong> a Herfindahl Index that is 0.044 lower, respectively. For firms run by younger<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s, the mean number <strong>of</strong> operating segments is 1.91 <strong>and</strong> the mean Herfindahl Index is 0.80.<br />

This means that older <strong>CEO</strong>s manage firms with 10.5% more operating segments <strong>and</strong> a 5.5%<br />

lower Herfindahl Index. One caveat <strong>of</strong> this test is that I am unable to discern whether it is older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s who diversify the firm’s operating segments or if it is because older <strong>CEO</strong>s manage firms<br />

that tend to be diversified that is driving the result. Although I am unable to make this<br />

distinction, the results from this table along with the results from Table V are consistent with the<br />

explanation that older <strong>CEO</strong>s tend to diversify their firms.<br />

In sum, the results <strong>of</strong> Tables V <strong>and</strong> VI suggest that older <strong>CEO</strong>s prefer to diversify the<br />

firm’s asset base. Since diversification is associated with lower firm value, these results further<br />

suggest that the investment behavior <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s creates agency costs between older managers<br />

<strong>and</strong> shareholders, not only through foregone pr<strong>of</strong>itable investments, but through firm<br />

diversification too.<br />

4.2.3 The relation between <strong>CEO</strong> age, investment behavior, <strong>and</strong> firm performance<br />

In this section, I analyze whether the investment behavior <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s translates into<br />

reduced shareholder wealth. If the lower investment level <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s truly represents an<br />

22


underinvestment problem, then the performance <strong>of</strong> firms managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s should be<br />

worse than the performance <strong>of</strong> firms managed by younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. I capture firm performance by<br />

examining abnormal stock returns, industry-adjusted sales growth, <strong>and</strong> industry-adjusted growth<br />

in operating income.<br />

Table VII reports the results <strong>of</strong> risk-adjusted portfolio abnormal stock returns. In Panel A,<br />

I construct a long portfolio that consists <strong>of</strong> equal weighted returns <strong>of</strong> all firms that have a<br />

younger <strong>CEO</strong>, where a younger <strong>CEO</strong> is defined as a <strong>CEO</strong> whose age is in the bottom tercile <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year. I then construct a short portfolio that consists <strong>of</strong> equal weighted<br />

returns <strong>of</strong> all firms that have an older <strong>CEO</strong>, where an older <strong>CEO</strong> is defined as a <strong>CEO</strong> whose age<br />

is in the top tercile <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year. Each month, I subtract the return on the short<br />

portfolio from the return on the long portfolio. Following Carhart (1997), I examine portfolio<br />

returns in excess <strong>of</strong> his four-factor model. I regress the differences in returns between the two<br />

portfolios on the CRSP value-weighted market return less the risk-free rate, SMB (small minus<br />

big), HML (high minus low), <strong>and</strong> MOM (momentum). SMB, HML, <strong>and</strong> MOM are the returns on<br />

zero-investment factor-mimicking portfolios designed to capture size, book-to-market, <strong>and</strong><br />

momentum effects, respectively. Alpha is the abnormal return in excess <strong>of</strong> passive investment in<br />

the factors. Following this strategy, an investor would have earned an abnormal return <strong>of</strong> 0.50%<br />

per month or 6.00% a year, suggesting that firms managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s significantly<br />

underperform firms run by younger <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

In Panel B, I investigate whether underinvestment is a source <strong>of</strong> the underperformance in<br />

firms that are managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s. I restrict the sample to firms managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s <strong>and</strong><br />

partition the sample into firms with above median growth opportunities <strong>and</strong> firms with below<br />

median growth opportunities, as approximated by the firm’s industry market-to-book ratio. For<br />

23


each group <strong>of</strong> firms, I construct a long portfolio that consists <strong>of</strong> equal weighted returns <strong>of</strong> firms<br />

that have a positive investment residual <strong>and</strong> a short portfolio that consists <strong>of</strong> equal weighted<br />

returns <strong>of</strong> firms that have a negative investment residual. I calculate a firm's investment residual<br />

by regressing the firm's investment rate on the firm's market-to-book ratio, logarithm <strong>of</strong> market<br />

value <strong>of</strong> assets, cash holdings, market leverage, pre-investment pr<strong>of</strong>itability, dividend yield, firm<br />

age, year fixed effects, <strong>and</strong> Fama <strong>and</strong> French 12 industries. Firms with a negative residual are<br />

then classified as firms with negative investment residuals, <strong>and</strong> firms with a positive residual are<br />

classified as firms with positive investment residuals. After applying the same methodology as in<br />

Panel A to measure abnormal returns, I find that this strategy generates an abnormal return <strong>of</strong><br />

0.38% per month or 4.52% a year in firms with above median growth opportunities <strong>and</strong> an<br />

abnormal return that is not significantly different from zero in firms with below median growth<br />

opportunities. However, even though the results are only significantly different from zero in the<br />

sample <strong>of</strong> high growth firms, the two results are not statistically different from one another at<br />

conventional levels. In sum, the results in Panel B <strong>of</strong> Table VII are consistent with the<br />

underinvestment by older <strong>CEO</strong>s being costly for shareholders when a firm has large growth<br />

opportunities.<br />

In Table VIII, I provide further evidence that firms with above median investment<br />

opportunities that are managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s underperform compared to firms managed by<br />

younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. In Models 1-4, I regress the firm’s industry-adjusted growth in sales from period<br />

t to period t+2 on the two proxies for <strong>CEO</strong> age, where industry adjusted-sales growth is the<br />

firm’s sales growth less the corresponding three-digit SIC industry’s median sales growth in a<br />

given year. In Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, I limit the sample to those firms with above median industry<br />

market-to-book ratios, <strong>and</strong> in Models 3 <strong>and</strong> 4, I restrict the sample to those firms with above<br />

24


median industry factor scores. The results indicate that firms managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s grow sales<br />

significantly slower than firms managed by younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. For example, the coefficient<br />

estimates from Model 1 imply that the sales growth <strong>of</strong> firms run by older <strong>CEO</strong>s is 6.05<br />

percentage points lower than firms run by younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. Since the average three-year sales<br />

growth <strong>of</strong> firms managed by younger <strong>CEO</strong>s is 22.28%, this means firms managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

grow their sales 27.16% more slowly.<br />

In Models 5-8 <strong>of</strong> this table, I regress the firm’s industry-adjusted growth in operating<br />

income before depreciation from period t to period t+2 on the two proxies for <strong>CEO</strong> age, where<br />

industry-adjusted operating income growth is the firm’s operating income growth less the<br />

corresponding three-digit SIC industry’s median operating income growth in a given year. In<br />

Models 5 <strong>and</strong> 6, I limit the sample to those firms with above median industry market-to-book<br />

ratios, <strong>and</strong> in Models 7 <strong>and</strong> 8, I restrict the sample to those firms with above median industry<br />

factor scores. The results indicate that firms managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s grow pr<strong>of</strong>its significantly<br />

slower than firms managed by younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. For example, the coefficient estimates from<br />

Model 5 imply that the operating income growth <strong>of</strong> firms run by older <strong>CEO</strong>s is 10.46 percentage<br />

points lower than firms run by younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. Since the average three-year operating income<br />

growth <strong>of</strong> firms managed by younger <strong>CEO</strong>s is 36.94%, this means firms managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

grow operating income 28.33% more slowly.<br />

In summary, the results <strong>of</strong> Tables VII <strong>and</strong> VIII indicate that differences in investment<br />

behavior between older <strong>and</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s in firms with above median investment opportunities<br />

translates into significant underperformance <strong>of</strong> firms managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s compared to firms<br />

managed by younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. These results imply that the effect that age has on the investment<br />

25


ehavior <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong>s is a potential source <strong>of</strong> agency costs <strong>and</strong> a potential source <strong>of</strong> destruction <strong>of</strong><br />

shareholder value.<br />

4.2.4 The relation between underinvestment <strong>and</strong> equity-based performance sensitive<br />

compensation<br />

The previous results show that in firms with above median growth opportunities older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s invest less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> this underinvestment is costly to shareholders. In this<br />

section, I test Hypothesis 3 <strong>and</strong> efficient contracting predictions that predict that firms with older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s provide their <strong>CEO</strong>s with more equity-based performance sensitive compensation to<br />

mitigate underinvestment problems. However, if older <strong>CEO</strong>s are awarded less equity-based<br />

performance sensitive compensation, this suggests that the compensation incentives <strong>of</strong> older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s are not structured in such a way as to align the interests <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s with those <strong>of</strong><br />

shareholders.<br />

It is possible that by tying an already risk-averse manager's wealth even more closely to<br />

the firm's performance, it will cause the <strong>CEO</strong> to become even more risk-averse <strong>and</strong> reluctant to<br />

engage in risky investments. 10 In Table IX, I examine whether within my sample, awarding older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s more equity-based performance sensitive compensation leads to greater investment levels.<br />

The dependent variable in all four models is the sum <strong>of</strong> the firm’s R&D expenditures <strong>and</strong> capital<br />

expenditures divided by the firm’s total assets. To capture any differential effect <strong>of</strong> awarded<br />

equity-based performance sensitive compensation on investment between older <strong>and</strong> younger<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s, I interact the two proxies for <strong>CEO</strong> age with the mean-adjusted logarithm <strong>of</strong> the total delta<br />

from option <strong>and</strong> restricted stock grants in given year. Since older <strong>CEO</strong>s only invest less than<br />

10 See Lambert, Larcker, <strong>and</strong> Verrecchia (1991), Carpenter (2000), <strong>and</strong> Parrino, Poteshman, <strong>and</strong> Weisbach (2005)<br />

for a further discussion on why providing <strong>CEO</strong>s with greater equity-based compensation can make them more rather<br />

than less risk-averse.<br />

26


younger <strong>CEO</strong>s in firms with above median investment opportunities, in Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, I limit<br />

the sample to those firms with above median industry market-to-book ratios, <strong>and</strong> in Models 3<br />

<strong>and</strong> 4, I restrict the sample to those firms with above median industry factor scores.<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> Table IX imply that when <strong>CEO</strong>s are awarded more equity-based<br />

performance sensitive compensation, both older <strong>and</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s invest more. Further, there<br />

is no statistically significant difference in the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> awarding equity-based<br />

performance sensitive compensation in reducing underinvestment by older or younger <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

The coefficient estimates from Model 1 imply that by doubling the delta awarded to older <strong>CEO</strong>s,<br />

older <strong>CEO</strong>s will increase their level <strong>of</strong> investment by approximately 0.23 (=0.403 - 0.176)<br />

percentage points. Since an older <strong>CEO</strong> with an average delta award invests 0.68 percentage<br />

points less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s do, a doubling <strong>of</strong> their delta award reduces the underinvestment<br />

problem by 33.8%. Thus, within my sample, efficient contracting predicts that awarding older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s more equity-based performance sensitive compensation will be a highly effective tool in<br />

mitigating the underinvestment problem.<br />

In the previous sections, I provide evidence that older <strong>CEO</strong>s underinvest compared to<br />

younger <strong>CEO</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> this underinvestment translates into worse firm performance. Therefore,<br />

Hypothesis 3 <strong>and</strong> efficient contracting predicts that older <strong>CEO</strong>s should be awarded more equity-<br />

based performance sensitive compensation to align older <strong>CEO</strong>s’ interests with those <strong>of</strong><br />

shareholders <strong>and</strong> to incentive older <strong>CEO</strong>s to pursue a more aggressive investment style.<br />

However, if older <strong>CEO</strong>s are awarded less equity-based performance sensitive compensation than<br />

younger <strong>CEO</strong>s, this result would be a potential explanation <strong>of</strong> why older <strong>CEO</strong>s appear to invest<br />

in a way that does not maximize firm value.<br />

27


In Table X, I test the efficient contracting prediction. The dependent variable in Models<br />

1-4 is the logarithm <strong>of</strong> one plus the delta <strong>of</strong> new option <strong>and</strong> restricted stock grants. I then run a<br />

Tobit regression <strong>and</strong> regress the dependent variable on the two proxies for <strong>CEO</strong> age <strong>and</strong> other<br />

control variables. In Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, I limit the sample to those firms with above median<br />

industry market-to-book ratios, <strong>and</strong> in Models 3 <strong>and</strong> 4, I restrict the sample to those firms with<br />

above median industry factor scores. The coefficient estimates represent marginal effects.<br />

The results in Table X show that, inconsistent with efficient contracting predictions, in<br />

firms with above median growth opportunities, older <strong>CEO</strong>s actually receive less equity-based<br />

performance sensitive compensation than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. For example, the coefficient estimates<br />

from Model 1 imply that the delta <strong>of</strong> equity grants awarded to older <strong>CEO</strong>s is approximately<br />

13.7% below that <strong>of</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. Thus, the compensation structure <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s does not<br />

appear to be designed to incentivize older <strong>CEO</strong>s to increase their level <strong>of</strong> investment. This result<br />

along with the result <strong>of</strong> Table IX suggests that one potential reason why older <strong>CEO</strong>s underinvest<br />

is that older <strong>CEO</strong>s do not receive enough equity-based performance sensitive compensation to<br />

incentivize them to expend more effort <strong>and</strong> invest more aggressively.<br />

A possible interpretation <strong>of</strong> the results <strong>of</strong> Table X is that the reason why older <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

receive less equity-based performance sensitive compensation is that they simply receive less<br />

total compensation. However, in untabulated results, I do not find any evidence that older <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

receive less total compensation than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

As a further test <strong>of</strong> whether the compensation structure <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s does not properly<br />

incentivize them to pursue more aggressive investment strategies, I examine the relation between<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> age <strong>and</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>’s annual cash salary. In Table XI, I regress the <strong>CEO</strong>’s annual cash salary<br />

on the two proxies for <strong>CEO</strong> age. In Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, I limit the sample to those firms with above<br />

28


median industry market-to-book ratios, <strong>and</strong> in Models 3 <strong>and</strong> 4, I restrict the sample to those firms<br />

with above median industry factor scores. The results show that older <strong>CEO</strong>s receive more annual<br />

cash salary than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s do. 11 The coefficient estimates from Model 1 imply that in firms<br />

with above median investment opportunities, an older <strong>CEO</strong> receives 5.2% more annual cash<br />

salary than do younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. This finding indicates that older <strong>CEO</strong>s do not receive less equity-<br />

based compensation because their overall pay level is lower, but instead, the lower level <strong>of</strong><br />

equity-based compensation is the result <strong>of</strong> a substitution <strong>of</strong> performance-sensitive compensation<br />

for compensation that is not sensitive to performance.<br />

The univariate results in Table II show that older <strong>CEO</strong>s tend to have longer tenures. Since<br />

a longer tenure is associated with an increase in the manager’s power <strong>and</strong> influence over the<br />

board, a potential explanation for why older <strong>CEO</strong>s receive less equity-based performance<br />

sensitive compensation <strong>and</strong> a greater annual cash salary than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s do is that older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s may have greater influence over the structure <strong>of</strong> their compensation due to power over the<br />

board. This would be consistent with managerial power theories that predict that since<br />

performance sensitive compensation ties more <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>'s wealth to the firm's performance,<br />

undiversified, risk-averse <strong>CEO</strong>s who have enough power over the board to influence the<br />

structure <strong>of</strong> their compensation will award themselves less performance sensitive compensation<br />

(e.g., Bebchuk, Fried, <strong>and</strong> Walker (2002); Bebchuk <strong>and</strong> Fried (2003); Cheng <strong>and</strong> Indjejikian<br />

(2009)).<br />

In summary, the results <strong>of</strong> this section imply that although the underinvestment problem<br />

associated with older <strong>CEO</strong>s could be mitigated by awarding them more equity-based<br />

performance sensitive compensation, older <strong>CEO</strong>s actually receive less equity-based performance<br />

11 The results are robust to using salary + bonus as the definition <strong>of</strong> cash compensation. I continue to find that older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s receive significantly less cash compensation than do younger <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

29


sensitive compensation. Moreover, older <strong>CEO</strong>s receive more annual cash salary than younger<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s do. Together, the results imply that the compensation structure <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s does not<br />

properly incentivize them to pursue more aggressive investment strategies that would be<br />

preferable to shareholders, <strong>and</strong> that the compensation structure <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s is likely a source<br />

<strong>of</strong> the underinvestment problem associated with older <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

5. Conclusion<br />

I provide evidence that the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong> significantly affects his investment behavior.<br />

Specifically, I find that older <strong>CEO</strong>s tend to invest less than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> that this finding<br />

is concentrated in firms with above median investment opportunities. The result suggests that<br />

older <strong>CEO</strong>s may be passing up investing in valuable projects, <strong>and</strong> thereby, creating agency costs<br />

through underinvestment.<br />

As further evidence that the investment behavior <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s is associated with the<br />

creation <strong>of</strong> agency costs, I document that when older <strong>CEO</strong>s make acquisitions, they are more<br />

likely to make diversifying acquisitions. In addition, I show that older <strong>CEO</strong>s are more likely to<br />

manage diversified firms.<br />

Next, I compare the performance <strong>of</strong> firms managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s compared to the<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> firms managed by younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. Consistent with the notion that the investment<br />

behavior <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s creates agency costs, I find that risk-adjusted stock returns, industry-<br />

adjusted sales growth, <strong>and</strong> industry-adjusted operating income growth are all lower in firms<br />

managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s compared to firms managed by younger <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

Finally, I examine whether the structure <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s’ compensation is designed to<br />

mitigate the underinvestment problem or if it is a potential source <strong>of</strong> the problem. In contrast to<br />

30


efficient contracting that predicts firms will award older <strong>CEO</strong>s more equity-based performance<br />

sensitive compensation to mitigate underinvestment, I document that older <strong>CEO</strong>s actually<br />

receive less equity-based performance sensitive compensation than younger <strong>CEO</strong>s. Moreover,<br />

older <strong>CEO</strong>s receive more non-performance sensitive cash compensation. These results suggest<br />

that instead <strong>of</strong> using compensation incentives to reduce the underinvestment problem, the less<br />

performance sensitive compensation awarded to older <strong>CEO</strong>s is likely a source <strong>of</strong> the<br />

underinvestment problem.<br />

Overall, my findings imply that, on average, the investment decisions made by older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s conflict with shareholders’ interests. In addition, my results suggest that the low level <strong>of</strong><br />

equity-based performance sensitive compensation provided to older <strong>CEO</strong>s is likely a potential<br />

source <strong>of</strong> the underinvestment problem associated with older <strong>CEO</strong>s.<br />

31


Bibliography<br />

Aggarwal, R. K., & Samwick, A. A. (2006). Empire-Builders <strong>and</strong> Shirkers: Investment, Firm<br />

Performance, <strong>and</strong> Managerial Incentives. Journal <strong>of</strong> Corporate Finance, 12(3), 489-515.<br />

Amihud, Y., & Lev, B. (1981). Risk Reduction as a Managerial Motive for Conglomerate<br />

Mergers. The Bell Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics, 12(2), 605-617.<br />

Antia, M., Pantzalis, C., & Park, J. (2010). <strong>CEO</strong> Decision Horizon <strong>and</strong> Firm Performance: An<br />

Empirical Investigation. Journal <strong>of</strong> Corporate Finance, 16(3), 288-301.<br />

Baber, W. R., Janakiraman, S. N., & Kang, S.-H. (1996). Investment Opportunities <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Structure <strong>of</strong> Executive Compensation. Journal <strong>of</strong> Accounting <strong>and</strong> Economics, 21(3), 297-<br />

318.<br />

Bamber, L. S., Jiang, J., & Wang, I. Y. (2010). What's My Style? The Influence <strong>of</strong> Top<br />

Managers on Voluntary Corporate Financial Disclosure. The Accounting Review, 85(4),<br />

1131-1162.<br />

Barker, V. L., & Mueller, G. C. (2002). <strong>CEO</strong> Characteristics <strong>and</strong> Firm R&D Spending.<br />

Management Science, 48(6), 782-801.<br />

Bebchuk, L. A., & Fried, J. M. (2003). Executive Compensation as an <strong>Age</strong>ncy Problem. Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Economic Perspectives, 17, 71-92.<br />

Bebchuk, L. A., Cremers, M. K., & Peyer, U. C. (2011). The <strong>CEO</strong> Pay Slice. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Financial Economics, 102(1), 199-221.<br />

Bebchuk, L., Fried, J. M., & Walker, D. I. (2002). Managerial Power <strong>and</strong> Rent Extraction in the<br />

Design <strong>of</strong> Executive Compensation. Harvard Law School John M. Olin Center for Law,<br />

Economics <strong>and</strong> Business Discussion Paper Series, Paper 366.<br />

Berger, P. G., & Ofek, E. (1995). Diversification's Effect on Firm Value. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial<br />

Economics, 37(1), 39-65.<br />

Bertr<strong>and</strong>, M., & Mullainathan, S. (2003). Enjoying the Quiet Life? Corporate Governance <strong>and</strong><br />

Managerial Preferences. Journal <strong>of</strong> Political Economy, 111(5), 1043-1075.<br />

Bertr<strong>and</strong>, M., & Schoar, A. (2003). Managing with Style: The Effect <strong>of</strong> Managers on Firm<br />

Policies. The Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics, 118(4), 1169-1208.<br />

Bizjak, J. M., Brickley, J. A., & Coles, J. L. (1993). Stock-Based Incentive Compensation <strong>and</strong><br />

Investment Behavior. Journal <strong>of</strong> Accounting <strong>and</strong> Economics, 16(1-3), 349-372.<br />

Black, F., & Scholes, M. (1973). The Pricing <strong>of</strong> Options <strong>and</strong> Corporate Liabilities. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Political Economy, 81(3), 637-654.<br />

32


Campbell, T. S., Chan, Y.-S., & Marino, A. M. (1989). Incentive Contracts for Managers Who<br />

Discover <strong>and</strong> Manage Investment Projects. Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic Behavior &<br />

Organization, 12(3), 353-364.<br />

Carhart, M. M. (1997). On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 52(1),<br />

57-82.<br />

Carpenter, J. N. (2000). Does Option Compensation Increase Managerial Risk Appetite? The<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 55(5), 2311-2331.<br />

Cassell, C. A., Huang, S. X., Sanchez, J. M., & Stuart, M. D. (2011). Seeking Safety: The<br />

Relation between <strong>CEO</strong> Inside Debt Holdings <strong>and</strong> the Riskiness <strong>of</strong> Firm Investment <strong>and</strong><br />

Financial Policies. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics, In Press.<br />

Cheng, S. (2004). R&D Expenditures <strong>and</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> Compensation. The Accounting Review, 79(2),<br />

305-328.<br />

Cheng, S., & Indjejikian, R. J. (2009). The Market for Corporate Control <strong>and</strong> <strong>CEO</strong><br />

Compensation: Complements or Substitutes. Contemporary Accounting Research, 26(3),<br />

701-728.<br />

Coles, J. L., Daniel, N. D., & Naveen, L. (2006). Managerial Incentives <strong>and</strong> Risk-Taking.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics, 79(2), 431-468.<br />

Core, J., & Guay, W. (1999). The Use <strong>of</strong> Equity Grants to Manage Optimal Equity Incentive<br />

Levels. Journal <strong>of</strong> Accounting <strong>and</strong> Economics, 28(2), 151-184.<br />

Core, J., & Guay, W. (2002). Estimating the Value <strong>of</strong> Employee Stock Option Portfolios <strong>and</strong><br />

Their Sensitivities to Price <strong>and</strong> Volatility. Journal <strong>of</strong> Accounting Research, 40(3), 613-<br />

630.<br />

Cremers, M., & Palia, D. (2010). Tenure <strong>and</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> pay. Working Paper.<br />

Cronqvist, H., Makhija, A. K., & Yonker, S. E. (2011). Behavioral Consistency in Corporate<br />

Finance: <strong>CEO</strong> Personal <strong>and</strong> Corporate Leverage. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics.<br />

Datta, S., Isk<strong>and</strong>ar-Datta, M., & Raman, K. (2001). Executive Compensation <strong>and</strong> Corporate<br />

Acquisition Decisions. The Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 56(6), 2299-2336.<br />

Dechow, P. M., & Sloan, R. G. (1991). Executive Incentives <strong>and</strong> the Horizon Problem: An<br />

Empirical Investigation. Journal <strong>of</strong> Accounting <strong>and</strong> Economics, 14(1), 51-89.<br />

Dechow, P. M., Hutton, A. P., & Sloan, R. G. (1996). Economic Consequences <strong>of</strong> Accounting<br />

for Stock-Based Compensation. Journal <strong>of</strong> Accounting Research, 34, 1-20.<br />

33


Denis, D. J., Denis, D. K., & Sarin, A. (1997). <strong>Age</strong>ncy Problems, Equity Ownership, <strong>and</strong><br />

Corporate Diversification. The Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 52(1), 135-160.<br />

Denis, D. J., Denis, D. K., & Yost, K. (2002). Global Diversification, Industrial Diversification,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Firm Value. The Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 57(5), 1951-1979.<br />

Duchin, R. (2010). Cash Holdings <strong>and</strong> Corporate Diversification. The Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 65(3),<br />

955-992.<br />

Faulkender, M. W., & Petersen, M. A. (2010). Investment <strong>and</strong> Capital Constraints: Repatriations<br />

Under the American Jobs Creation Act. Working Paper.<br />

Garvey, G. T., & Milbourn, T. T. (2006). Asymmetric Benchmarking in Compensation:<br />

Executives are Rewarded for Good Luck but not Penalized for Bad. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial<br />

Economics, 82(1), 197-225.<br />

Gaver, J. J., & Gaver, K. M. (1993). Additional Evidence on the Association between the<br />

Investment Opportunity Set <strong>and</strong> Corporate Financing, Dividend, <strong>and</strong> Compensation<br />

Policies. Journal <strong>of</strong> Accounting <strong>and</strong> Economics, 16(1-3), 125-160.<br />

Gompers, P., Ishii, J., & Metrick, A. (2003). Corporate Governance <strong>and</strong> Equity Prices. The<br />

Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics, 118(1), 107-156.<br />

Graham, J. R., Harvey, C. R., & Puri, M. (2010). Managerial Attitudes <strong>and</strong> Corporate Actions.<br />

Working Paper.<br />

Grinstein, Y., & Hribar, P. (2004). <strong>CEO</strong> Compensation <strong>and</strong> Incentives: Evidence from M&A<br />

Bonuses. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics, 73(1), 119-143.<br />

Guay, W. R. (1999). The Sensitivity <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> Wealth to Equity Risk: An Analysis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Magnitude <strong>and</strong> Determinants. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics, 53(1), 43-71.<br />

Hirshleifer, D., & Suh, Y. (1992). Risk, Managerial Effort, <strong>and</strong> Project Choice. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Financial Intermediation, 2(3), 308-345.<br />

Holmstrom, B. (1999). Managerial Incentive Problems: A Dynamic Perspective. The Review <strong>of</strong><br />

Economic Studies, 66(1), 169-182.<br />

Jensen, M. C. (1986). <strong>Age</strong>ncy <strong>Costs</strong> <strong>of</strong> Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, <strong>and</strong> Takeovers. The<br />

American Economic Review, 76(2), 323-329.<br />

Kothari, S., Laguerre, T. E., & Leone, A. J. (2002). Capitalization versus Expensing: Evidence<br />

on the Uncertainty <strong>of</strong> Future Earnings from Capital Expenditures versus R&D Outlays.<br />

Review <strong>of</strong> Accounting Studies, 7(4), 355-382.<br />

34


Lambert, R. A. (1986). Executive Effort <strong>and</strong> Selection <strong>of</strong> Risky Projects. The RAND Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Economics, 17(1), 77-88.<br />

Lambert, R. A., Larcker, D. F., & Verrecchia, R. E. (1991). Portfolio Considerations in Valuing<br />

Executive Compensation. Journal <strong>of</strong> Accounting Research, 29(1), 129-149.<br />

Levi, M., Li, K., & Zhang, F. (2010). Deal or No Deal: Hormones <strong>and</strong> the Mergers <strong>and</strong><br />

Acquisitions Game. Management Science, 56(9), 1462-1483.<br />

Li, X., Low, A., & Makhija, A. K. (2011). Career Concerns <strong>and</strong> the Busy Life <strong>of</strong> the Young<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>. Working Paper.<br />

Malmendier, U., & Nagel, S. (2011). Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect<br />

Risk Taking? The Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics, 126(1), 373-416.<br />

Malmendier, U., Tate, G., & Yan, J. (2011). Overconfidence <strong>and</strong> Early-Life Experiences: The<br />

Effect <strong>of</strong> Managerial Traits on Corporate Financial Policies. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 66(5),<br />

1687-1733.<br />

Mansi, S. A., & Reeb, D. M. (2002). Corporate Diversification: What Gets Discounted. The<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 57(5), 2167-2183.<br />

Masulis, R. W., Wang, C., & Xie, F. (2007). Corporate Governance <strong>and</strong> Acquirer Returns.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 62(4), 1851-1889.<br />

Merton, R. C. (1973). Theory <strong>of</strong> Rational Option Pricing. The Bell Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics <strong>and</strong><br />

Management Science, 4(1), 141-183.<br />

Murphy, K. J. (1986). Incentives, learning, <strong>and</strong> compensation: A theoretical <strong>and</strong> empirical<br />

investigation. The RAND Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics, 17(1), 59-76.<br />

Parrino, R., Poteshman, A. M., & Weisbach, M. S. (2005). Measuring Investment Distortions<br />

when Risk-Averse Managers Decide Whether to Undertake Risky Projects. Financial<br />

Management, 34(1), 21-60.<br />

Prendergast, C., & Stole, L. (1996). Impetuous Youngsters <strong>and</strong> Jaded Old-Timers: Acquiring a<br />

Reputation for Learning. Journal <strong>of</strong> Political Economy, 104(6), 1105-1134.<br />

Rajgopal, S., & Shevlin, T. (2002). Empirical Evidence on the Relation between Stock Option<br />

Compensation <strong>and</strong> Risk Taking. Journal <strong>of</strong> Accounting <strong>and</strong> Economics, 33(2), 145-171.<br />

Roberts, S. B., & Rosenberg, I. (2006). Nutrition <strong>and</strong> Aging: Changes in the Regulation <strong>of</strong><br />

Energy Metabolism With Aging. Physiological Reviews, 86(2), 651-667.<br />

35


Ryan, H. E., & Wiggins, R. A. (2001). The Influence <strong>of</strong> Firm- <strong>and</strong> Manager-Specific<br />

Characteristics on the Structure <strong>of</strong> Executive Compensation. Journal <strong>of</strong> Corporate<br />

Finance, 7(2), 101-123.<br />

Scharfstein, D. S., & Stein, J. C. (1990). Herd Behavior <strong>and</strong> Investment. The American<br />

Economic Review, 80(3), 465-479.<br />

Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1989). Management Entrenchment: The Case <strong>of</strong> Manager-<br />

Specific Investments. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics, 25(1), 123-139.<br />

Smith, C. W., & Watts, R. L. (1982). Incentive <strong>and</strong> Tax Effects <strong>of</strong> Executive Compensation<br />

Plans. Australian Journal <strong>of</strong> Management, 7(2), 139-157.<br />

Taylor, R. N. (1975). <strong>Age</strong> <strong>and</strong> Experience as Determinants <strong>of</strong> Managerial Information<br />

Processing <strong>and</strong> Decision Making Performance. Academy <strong>of</strong> Management, 18(1), 74-81.<br />

Yermack, D. (1995). Do Corporations Award <strong>CEO</strong> Stock Options Effectively? Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Financial Economics, 39(2-3), 237-269.<br />

Yim, S. (2010). The Acquisitiveness <strong>of</strong> Youth: <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> <strong>and</strong> Acquisition Behavior. Working<br />

Paper.<br />

Zheng, Y. (2010). The Effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> Tenure on <strong>CEO</strong> Compensation: Evidence from Inside<br />

<strong>CEO</strong>s vs Outside <strong>CEO</strong>s. Managerial Finance, 36(10), 832-859.<br />

36


Table I<br />

Descriptive Statistics<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong>s are defined as <strong>CEO</strong>s whose age is in the top tercile <strong>of</strong> all <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year. Younger <strong>CEO</strong>s are defined as <strong>CEO</strong>s whose age is in the bottom two terciles <strong>of</strong> all<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year. <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> is the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>. Tenure is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the <strong>CEO</strong> has been <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm. Founder is an indicator variable that equals one if<br />

the <strong>CEO</strong> was <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm when the firm first began trading <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. Investment Activity is (capital expenditures + R&D expenses) / total assets. Firm Market-to-<br />

Book equals (book value <strong>of</strong> assets + the market value <strong>of</strong> equity - the book value <strong>of</strong> equity - balance sheet deferred taxes) / total assets. Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets equals (market<br />

value equity + book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) <strong>and</strong> is in millions. Cash Holding equals (book value <strong>of</strong> cash <strong>and</strong> short-term investments) / total assets.<br />

Market Leverage equals (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) / (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities + market value <strong>of</strong> common shares).<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets equals (EBITDA + R&D expenses + advertising expenses) / total assets. Dividend Yield is the average dividend yield over the current year<br />

<strong>and</strong> the previous two years. Firm <strong>Age</strong> is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the firm has been publicly trading. Industry Adjusted Sales Growth is the firm's sales growth over the next three<br />

years less the median three-digit SIC industry sales growth. Industry Adjusted Operating Income Growth is the firm's growth in operating income before depreciation over the<br />

next three years less the median three-digit-SIC industry growth rate. Industry Market-to-Book is the median market-to-book ratio <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given<br />

year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. High Industry MB is an indicator variable that is equal to one if a firm's corresponding Industry MB is above the<br />

median. Industry Factor Score is the median Factor Score <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Factor<br />

Score is a common factor extracted from a firm's investment intensity, market-to-book value <strong>of</strong> assets, R&D expenditures, <strong>and</strong> growth rate <strong>of</strong> market value <strong>of</strong> assets (Baber,<br />

Janakiraman, <strong>and</strong> Kang (1996). High Industry Factor Score is an indicator variable that is equal to one if a firm's corresponding Industry Factor Score is above the median.<br />

Portfolio Delta is a thous<strong>and</strong> dollar change in <strong>CEO</strong> wealth given a 1% change in stock price. New Delta is the sum <strong>of</strong> the Delta from option awards <strong>and</strong> the Delta <strong>of</strong> stock awards.<br />

Total Compensation equals (Salary + Bonus + Other Annual Compensation + Restricted Stock Grants + LTIP Payouts + All Other Compensation + Value <strong>of</strong> Option Grants) <strong>and</strong> is<br />

in thous<strong>and</strong>s. Salary is annual <strong>CEO</strong> salary <strong>and</strong> is in thous<strong>and</strong>s. Equity Compensation is the sum <strong>of</strong> the value <strong>of</strong> option <strong>and</strong> stock awards <strong>and</strong> is in thous<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

Observations Mean Std. Dev. P25 Median P75<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> 13769 54.74 6.97 50.00 55.00 59.00<br />

Tenure 13769 6.819 6.377 2.000 5.000 9.000<br />

Founder 13769 0.110 0.312 0.000 0.000 0.000<br />

Investment 13769 10.60 9.46 4.27 7.85 13.62<br />

Firm Market-to-Book 13769 2.059 1.400 1.221 1.609 2.337<br />

Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets 13769 9280 27908 750 1904 5997<br />

Cash Holdings 13769 0.146 0.173 0.022 0.073 0.211<br />

Market Leverage 13769 0.198 0.195 0.033 0.148 0.298<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets 13769 0.190 0.110 0.121 0.176 0.244<br />

Dividend Yield 13769 0.010 0.014 0.000 0.002 0.016<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> 13769 24.16 19.69 9.00 18.00 33.00<br />

Industry Adjusted 3-Year Sales Growth 12435 0.136 0.658 -0.182 0.000 0.266<br />

Industry Adjusted 3-Year Operating Income Growth 12231 0.253 1.114 -0.209 0.080 0.555<br />

Industry Market-to-Book 13769 2.077 0.808 1.470 1.886 2.476<br />

Industry Factor Score 13769 0.046 0.544 -0.341 -0.146 0.365<br />

Portfolio Delta 13769 599.0 1055.3 100.1 245.8 612.0<br />

New Delta 12760 52.04 85.59 5.25 21.08 59.31<br />

Total Compensation 13769 4989 5959 1471 2902 5926<br />

Salary 13769 773.0 363.3 503.5 715.8 981.1<br />

Equity Compensation 13769 2925 4413 316 1317 3550


Table II<br />

Univariate Results Comparing Firms with Older <strong>CEO</strong>s to Firms with Younger <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong>s are defined as <strong>CEO</strong>s whose age is in the top tercile <strong>of</strong> all <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year. Younger <strong>CEO</strong>s are defined as <strong>CEO</strong>s whose age is in the bottom two terciles <strong>of</strong> all <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a<br />

given year. <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> is the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>. Tenure is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the <strong>CEO</strong> has been <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm. Founder is an indicator variable that equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong> was <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm<br />

when the firm first began trading <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. Investment Activity is (capital expenditures + R&D expenses) / total assets. Firm Market-to-Book equals (book value <strong>of</strong> assets + the market<br />

value <strong>of</strong> equity - the book value <strong>of</strong> equity - balance sheet deferred taxes) / total assets. Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets equals (market value equity + book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current<br />

liabilities) <strong>and</strong> is in millions. Cash Holding equals (book value <strong>of</strong> cash <strong>and</strong> short-term investments) / total assets. Market Leverage equals (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities)<br />

/ (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities + market value <strong>of</strong> common shares). Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets equals (EBITDA + R&D expenses + advertising expenses) /<br />

total assets. Dividend Yield is the average dividend yield over the current year <strong>and</strong> the previous two years. Firm <strong>Age</strong> is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the firm has been publicly trading. Industry<br />

Adjusted Sales Growth is the firm's sales growth over the next three years less the median three-digit SIC industry sales growth. Industry Adjusted Operating Income Growth is the firm's growth<br />

in operating income before depreciation over the next three years less the median three-digit-SIC industry growth rate. Industry Market-to-Book is the median market-to-book ratio <strong>of</strong> a firm's<br />

corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. High Industry MB is an indicator variable that is equal to one if a firm's corresponding Industry<br />

MB is above the median. Industry Factor Score is the median Factor Score <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Factor<br />

Score is a common factor extracted from a firm's investment intensity, market-to-book value <strong>of</strong> assets, R&D expenditures, <strong>and</strong> growth rate <strong>of</strong> market value <strong>of</strong> assets (Baber, Janakiraman, <strong>and</strong> Kang<br />

(1996). High Industry Factor Score is an indicator variable that is equal to one if a firm's corresponding Industry Factor Score is above the median. Portfolio Delta is a thous<strong>and</strong> dollar change in<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> wealth given a 1% change in stock price. New Delta is the sum <strong>of</strong> the Delta from option awards <strong>and</strong> the Delta <strong>of</strong> stock awards. Total Compensation equals (Salary + Bonus + Other Annual<br />

Compensation + Restricted Stock Grants + LTIP Payouts + All Other Compensation + Value <strong>of</strong> Option Grants) <strong>and</strong> is in thous<strong>and</strong>s. Salary is annual <strong>CEO</strong> salary <strong>and</strong> is in thous<strong>and</strong>s. Equity<br />

Compensation is the sum <strong>of</strong> the value <strong>of</strong> option <strong>and</strong> stock awards <strong>and</strong> is in thous<strong>and</strong>s. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, <strong>and</strong> 1% levels respectively.<br />

Firms with Younger <strong>CEO</strong>s Firms with Older <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

Observations Mean Observations Mean Difference p-Value<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> 9519 51.27 4250 62.52 -11.25*** 0.000<br />

Tenure 9519 5.559 4250 9.643 -4.084*** 0.000<br />

Founder 9519 0.100 4250 0.131 -0.031*** 0.000<br />

Investment 9519 11.14 4250 9.38 1.76*** 0.000<br />

Firm Market-to-Book 9519 2.120 4250 1.922 0.198*** 0.000<br />

Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets 9519 8450 4250 11137 -2686*** 0.000<br />

Cash Holdings 9519 0.158 4250 0.12 0.038*** 0.000<br />

Market Leverage 9519 0.191 4250 0.214 -0.023*** 0.000<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets 9519 0.194 4250 0.183 0.011*** 0.000<br />

Dividend Yield 9519 0.009 4250 0.012 -0.003*** 0.000<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> 9519 22.56 4250 27.75 -5.186*** 0.000<br />

Industry Adjusted 3-Year Sales Growth 8576 0.161 3859 0.083 0.078*** 0.000<br />

Industry Adjusted 3-Year Operating Income Growth 8421 0.277 3810 0.201 0.076*** 0.000<br />

High Industry Market-to-Book 9519 0.515 4250 0.442 0.073*** 0.000<br />

High Industry Factor Score 9519 0.511 4250 0.454 0.058*** 0.000<br />

Portfolio Delta 9519 552.8 4250 702.6 -149.8*** 0.000<br />

New Delta 8874 51.87 3886 52.44 -0.568 0.730<br />

Total Compensation 9519 4843 4250 5317 -474.9*** 0.000<br />

Salary 9519 735.6 4250 857.0 -121.4*** 0.000<br />

Equity Compensation 9519 2977 4250 2810 167.1** 0.040<br />

38


Table III<br />

Panel A: The Relation between <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> <strong>and</strong> Investment Activity<br />

The dependent variable is measured in time period t, whereas the independent variables are measured in time period t-1. The dependent variable in Panel<br />

A <strong>and</strong> Panel B is Investment Activity. Investment Activity is (capital expenditures + R&D expenses) / total assets. In Panel C, the dependent variable is<br />

R&D expenses / total assets. In Panel D, the dependent variable is capital expenditures / total assets. Oldest <strong>CEO</strong> is an indicator variable that equals one if<br />

the <strong>CEO</strong>'s age is in the top third <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> is the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>. Industry Market-to-Book is the median<br />

market-to-book ratio <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. High Industry MB is an<br />

indicator variable that is equal to one if a firm's corresponding Industry MB is above the median. Industry Factor Score is the median Factor Score <strong>of</strong> a<br />

firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Factor Score is a common factor extracted from a<br />

firm's investment intensity, market-to-book value <strong>of</strong> assets, R&D expenditures, <strong>and</strong> growth rate <strong>of</strong> market value <strong>of</strong> assets (Baber, Janakiraman, <strong>and</strong> Kang<br />

(1996). High Industry Factor Score is an indicator variable that is equal to one if a firm's corresponding Industry Factor Score is above the median.<br />

Portfolio Delta is a thous<strong>and</strong> dollar change in <strong>CEO</strong> wealth given a 1% change in stock price. Tenure is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the <strong>CEO</strong> has been <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

the firm. Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets equals (market value equity + book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) <strong>and</strong> is in millions. Firm Market-to-<br />

Book equals (book value <strong>of</strong> assets + the market value <strong>of</strong> equity - the book value <strong>of</strong> equity - balance sheet deferred taxes) / total assets. Cash Holding<br />

equals (book value <strong>of</strong> cash <strong>and</strong> short-term investments) / total assets. Market Leverage equals (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) /<br />

(book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities + market value <strong>of</strong> common shares). Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets equals (EBITDA +<br />

R&D expenses + advertising expenses) / total assets. Dividend Yield is the average dividend yield over the current year <strong>and</strong> the previous two years.<br />

Founder is an indicator variable that equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong> was <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm when the firm first began trading <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. Firm <strong>Age</strong> is the<br />

number <strong>of</strong> years that the firm has been publicly trading. Industry fixed effects are measured using the Fama <strong>and</strong> French 12 industry breakdown. St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

errors are clustered by firm. T-statistics are presented in parentheses. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, <strong>and</strong> 1% levels respectively.<br />

Investment Opportunity Proxy<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> -0.460* -0.086 -0.005<br />

(-1.91) (-0.33) (-0.02)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> -0.062*** -0.023 -0.013<br />

(-3.01) (-0.97) (-0.57)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> * High Industry MB -0.807**<br />

(-2.02)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> * High Industry MB -0.078**<br />

(-2.43)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> * High Industry Factor Score -0.970**<br />

(-2.34)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> * High Industry Factor Score -0.095***<br />

(-2.93)<br />

High Industry MB 0.486** 0.471** 0.746*** 0.499**<br />

(2.10) (2.04) (2.73) (2.14)<br />

High Industry Factor Score 1.378*** 1.107***<br />

(4.46) (4.21)<br />

Log 1+Portfolio Delta -0.104 -0.123 -0.106 -0.129 -0.100 -0.121<br />

(-0.73) (-0.87) (-0.75) (-0.91) (-0.71) (-0.86)<br />

Log Tenure 0.265 0.384* 0.266 0.388** 0.257 0.378*<br />

(1.40) (1.95) (1.40) (1.97) (1.36) (1.92)<br />

Log Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets -0.412*** -0.385*** -0.410*** -0.383*** -0.420*** -0.396***<br />

(-2.95) (-2.75) (-2.94) (-2.74) (-3.00) (-2.84)<br />

Firm Market-to-Book 1.334*** 1.321*** 1.332*** 1.315*** 1.329*** 1.309***<br />

(7.21) (7.13) (7.20) (7.09) (7.19) (7.07)<br />

Cash Holdings 9.289*** 9.169*** 9.225*** 9.052*** 9.091*** 8.894***<br />

(7.07) (6.99) (7.03) (6.92) (6.94) (6.80)<br />

Market Leverage -0.491 -0.540 -0.499 -0.554 -0.421 -0.477<br />

(-0.65) (-0.72) (-0.66) (-0.73) (-0.56) (-0.64)<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets 15.708*** 15.689*** 15.709*** 15.726*** 15.790*** 15.815***<br />

(8.50) (8.49) (8.51) (8.53) (8.57) (8.59)<br />

Dividend Yield -66.194*** -65.254*** -66.513*** -65.944*** -64.944*** -64.441***<br />

(-7.16) (-7.07) (-7.19) (-7.15) (-6.95) (-6.91)<br />

Founder <strong>CEO</strong> -0.558 -0.524 -0.574 -0.556 -0.572 -0.559<br />

(-1.16) (-1.09) (-1.19) (-1.16) (-1.19) (-1.17)<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> -0.009 -0.007 -0.009 -0.007 -0.009 -0.007<br />

(-1.20) (-0.98) (-1.19) (-0.97) (-1.19) (-0.96)<br />

Intercept 6.145*** 5.716*** 6.031*** 5.763*** 5.987*** 5.711***<br />

(6.30) (5.73) (6.20) (5.79) (6.19) (5.77)<br />

Observations 13769 13769 13769 13769 13769 13769<br />

Adjusted R 2 High Industry Market-to-Book High Industry Factor Score<br />

0.393 0.395 0.394 0.395 0.395 0.397<br />

Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

39


Table III - Continued<br />

Panel B: The Relation between Tenure, <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong>, <strong>and</strong> Investment Activity<br />

High Industry Market-to-Book<br />

Investment Opportunity Proxy<br />

High Industry Factor Score<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> -0.408 -0.415<br />

(-1.10) (-1.11)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> -0.090*** -0.097***<br />

(-2.97) (-3.25)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> * Log Tenure -1.392*** -1.377***<br />

(-3.18) (-3.10)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> * Log Tenure -0.071*** -0.063**<br />

(-2.70) (-2.37)<br />

High Industry MB 0.700** 0.681**<br />

(2.22) (2.19)<br />

High Industry Factor Score 3.672*** 3.692***<br />

(5.60) (5.63)<br />

Log 1+Portfolio Delta -0.094 -0.123 -0.119 -0.139<br />

(-0.39) (-0.52) (-0.51) (-0.60)<br />

Log Tenure 0.552 0.345 0.486 0.295<br />

(1.47) (1.02) (1.34) (0.91)<br />

Log Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets -0.228 -0.205 -0.209 -0.194<br />

(-1.11) (-1.01) (-0.99) (-0.92)<br />

Cash Holdings 15.496*** 15.306*** 14.171*** 13.935***<br />

(10.14) (9.95) (10.16) (9.91)<br />

Market Leverage -2.192 -2.177 -2.151* -2.114*<br />

(-1.55) (-1.54) (-1.76) (-1.72)<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets 21.117*** 21.107*** 21.911*** 21.885***<br />

(10.11) (10.13) (10.37) (10.37)<br />

Dividend Yield -120.496*** -119.137*** -126.881*** -124.860***<br />

(-6.53) (-6.49) (-6.34) (-6.24)<br />

Founder <strong>CEO</strong> -0.283 -0.284 -0.344 -0.361<br />

(-0.41) (-0.41) (-0.51) (-0.53)<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> -0.014 -0.010 -0.025** -0.021*<br />

(-1.15) (-0.84) (-2.26) (-1.91)<br />

Intercept 7.186*** 7.103*** 9.370*** 9.075***<br />

(4.90) (4.88) (5.78) (5.61)<br />

Observations 6785 6785 6798 6798<br />

Adjusted R 2 0.373 0.376 0.373 0.376<br />

Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

40


Table III - Continued<br />

Panel C: The Relation between <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> <strong>and</strong> R&D Expenditures<br />

Investment Opportunity Proxy<br />

High Industry Market-to-Book High Industry Factor Score<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> -0.207 0.155 0.203<br />

(-1.06) (1.18) (1.60)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> -0.030* 0.007 0.013<br />

(-1.71) (0.62) (1.20)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> * High Industry MB -0.782**<br />

(-2.31)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> * High Industry MB -0.074***<br />

(-2.74)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> * High Industry Factor Score -0.881**<br />

(-2.56)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> * High Industry Factor Score -0.085***<br />

(-3.13)<br />

High Industry MB 0.633*** 0.625*** 0.885*** 0.651***<br />

(4.19) (4.13) (4.64) (4.30)<br />

High Industry Factor Score 1.460*** 1.217***<br />

(6.63) (6.79)<br />

Log 1+Portfolio Delta -0.160 -0.169 -0.161 -0.174 -0.155 -0.166<br />

(-1.41) (-1.48) (-1.43) (-1.53) (-1.38) (-1.47)<br />

Log Tenure 0.046 0.107 0.047 0.111 0.038 0.100<br />

(0.28) (0.61) (0.28) (0.63) (0.23) (0.57)<br />

Log Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets -0.376*** -0.362*** -0.374*** -0.361*** -0.384*** -0.374***<br />

(-2.90) (-2.74) (-2.89) (-2.73) (-2.98) (-2.85)<br />

Firm Market-to-Book 1.098*** 1.092*** 1.096*** 1.086*** 1.097*** 1.085***<br />

(4.93) (4.89) (4.92) (4.85) (4.92) (4.84)<br />

Cash Holdings 14.618*** 14.557*** 14.556*** 14.446*** 14.416*** 14.286***<br />

(11.07) (11.01) (11.04) (10.96) (10.97) (10.87)<br />

Market Leverage 2.490*** 2.466*** 2.483*** 2.452*** 2.541*** 2.509***<br />

(4.74) (4.70) (4.73) (4.67) (4.86) (4.80)<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets 4.904** 4.892** 4.905** 4.928** 4.999** 5.028**<br />

(2.38) (2.38) (2.38) (2.39) (2.43) (2.44)<br />

Dividend Yield -14.448** -13.965** -14.762** -14.625** -13.083** -12.985**<br />

(-2.48) (-2.41) (-2.53) (-2.51) (-2.27) (-2.26)<br />

Founder <strong>CEO</strong> -0.869** -0.852** -0.885** -0.883** -0.884** -0.886**<br />

(-2.30) (-2.26) (-2.35) (-2.34) (-2.35) (-2.35)<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> 0.013** 0.014** 0.013** 0.014** 0.013** 0.014***<br />

(2.35) (2.55) (2.37) (2.57) (2.38) (2.59)<br />

Intercept 0.135 -0.075 0.025 -0.031 0.019 -0.053<br />

(0.15) (-0.08) (0.03) (-0.03) (0.02) (-0.06)<br />

Observations 13765 13765 13765 13765 13765 13765<br />

Adjusted R 2 0.412 0.412 0.412 0.413 0.414 0.415<br />

Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

41


Table III - Continued<br />

Panel D: The Relation between <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> <strong>and</strong> Capital Expenditures<br />

High Industry Market-to-Book<br />

Investment Opportunity Proxy<br />

High Industry Factor Score<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> -0.206 -0.165 -0.119 -0.119<br />

(-1.09) (-0.67) (-0.47) (-0.47)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> -0.034** -0.022<br />

(-2.01) (-0.97)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> * High Industry MB -0.087<br />

(-0.29)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> * High Industry MB -0.024<br />

(-0.87)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> * High Industry Factor Score -0.180 -0.180<br />

(-0.58) (-0.58)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> * High Industry Factor Score<br />

High Industry MB -0.156 -0.166 -0.128 -0.157<br />

(-0.75) (-0.79) (-0.54) (-0.75)<br />

High Industry Factor Score -0.015 -0.015<br />

(-0.05) (-0.05)<br />

Log 1+Portfolio Delta 0.125 0.114 0.125 0.112 0.124 0.124<br />

(1.12) (1.03) (1.12) (1.01) (1.12) (1.12)<br />

Log Tenure 0.132 0.207 0.132 0.209 0.131 0.131<br />

(0.93) (1.42) (0.93) (1.43) (0.92) (0.92)<br />

Log Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets -0.205* -0.190* -0.205* -0.189* -0.206* -0.206*<br />

(-1.82) (-1.68) (-1.82) (-1.68) (-1.82) (-1.82)<br />

Firm Market-to-Book 0.641*** 0.634*** 0.641*** 0.632*** 0.636*** 0.636***<br />

(5.89) (5.84) (5.89) (5.83) (5.85) (5.85)<br />

Cash Holdings -4.124*** -4.198*** -4.130*** -4.234*** -4.132*** -4.132***<br />

(-6.14) (-6.23) (-6.13) (-6.24) (-6.12) (-6.12)<br />

Market Leverage -2.272*** -2.302*** -2.272*** -2.306*** -2.242*** -2.242***<br />

(-3.69) (-3.74) (-3.69) (-3.75) (-3.68) (-3.68)<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets 9.196*** 9.178*** 9.196*** 9.189*** 9.185*** 9.185***<br />

(7.61) (7.57) (7.61) (7.60) (7.62) (7.62)<br />

Dividend Yield -50.810*** -50.209*** -50.845*** -50.423*** -50.886*** -50.886***<br />

(-6.16) (-6.10) (-6.16) (-6.13) (-6.10) (-6.10)<br />

Founder <strong>CEO</strong> 0.297 0.318 0.295 0.308 0.297 0.297<br />

(0.72) (0.77) (0.71) (0.74) (0.72) (0.72)<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> -0.020*** -0.019*** -0.020*** -0.019*** -0.020*** -0.020***<br />

(-3.35) (-3.20) (-3.35) (-3.20) (-3.34) (-3.34)<br />

Intercept 6.355*** 6.111*** 6.343*** 6.125*** 6.292*** 6.292***<br />

(9.09) (8.63) (9.07) (8.66) (9.07) (9.07)<br />

Observations 13765 13765 13765 13765 13765 13765<br />

Adjusted R 2 0.312 0.313 0.312 0.313 0.312 0.312<br />

Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

42


Table IV<br />

The Relation between Changes in Investment Activity <strong>and</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> Turnover<br />

The dependent variable is the change in investment activity around a <strong>CEO</strong> turnover. Investment Activity is (capital expenditures<br />

+ R&D expenses) / total assets. In Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, the dependent variable is the investment rate in the year after the <strong>CEO</strong> is hired<br />

minus the investment rate in the year before the <strong>CEO</strong> was hired. In Models 3 <strong>and</strong> 4, the dependent variable is the 2-year average<br />

investment rate over the two years after the <strong>CEO</strong> is hired minus the 2-year average investment rate over the two years before the<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> was hired. <strong>Age</strong> Difference is the age <strong>of</strong> the newly hired <strong>CEO</strong> less the age <strong>of</strong> the replaced <strong>CEO</strong>. Largest <strong>Age</strong> Difference is an<br />

indicator variable equal to one if <strong>Age</strong> difference is in the highest tercile. The highest tercile consists <strong>of</strong> firms where a younger<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> was replaced by an older <strong>CEO</strong>. Medium <strong>Age</strong> Difference is an indicator variable equal to one if <strong>Age</strong> difference is in the<br />

second tercile. Market-to-Book equals (book value <strong>of</strong> assets + the market value <strong>of</strong> equity - the book value <strong>of</strong> equity - balance<br />

sheet deferred taxes) / total assets. Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets equals (market value equity + book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in<br />

current liabilities) <strong>and</strong> is in millions. Cash Holding equals (book value <strong>of</strong> cash <strong>and</strong> short-term investments) / total assets. Market<br />

Leverage equals (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) / (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current<br />

liabilities + market value <strong>of</strong> common shares). Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets equals (EBITDA + R&D expenses +<br />

advertising expenses) / total assets. Dividend Yield is the average dividend yield over the current year <strong>and</strong> the previous two<br />

years. In Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, the change variables are calculated by taking the variable in year after the <strong>CEO</strong> is hired minus the<br />

variable in the year before the <strong>CEO</strong> was hired. In Models 3 <strong>and</strong> 4, the change variables are calculated by taking the 2-year<br />

average <strong>of</strong> the variable over the two years after the <strong>CEO</strong> is hired minus the 2-year average <strong>of</strong> the variable over the two years<br />

before the <strong>CEO</strong> was hired. Firm <strong>Age</strong> is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the firm has been publicly trading in the year <strong>of</strong> the turnover.<br />

Industry fixed effects are measured using the Fama <strong>and</strong> French 12 industry breakdown. St<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered by firm. Tstatistics<br />

are presented in parentheses. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, <strong>and</strong> 1% levels respectively.<br />

Change in Investment Activity<br />

2-Year Average Change in Investment<br />

Activity<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

<strong>Age</strong> Difference -0.049** -0.063***<br />

(-2.20) (-3.13)<br />

Medium <strong>Age</strong> Difference -0.195 -0.110<br />

(-0.42) (-0.24)<br />

Largest <strong>Age</strong> Difference -1.319*** -1.494***<br />

(-2.82) (-3.20)<br />

Change in Market-to-Book 0.619*** 0.616*** 0.172 0.170<br />

(4.27) (4.31) (1.08) (1.08)<br />

Change in Log Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets -0.825 -0.814 -1.308** -1.275**<br />

(-1.34) (-1.33) (-2.38) (-2.33)<br />

Change in Cash Holdings 3.880 3.897 4.590 4.608<br />

(1.21) (1.22) (1.38) (1.39)<br />

Change in Market Leverage 4.809 4.796 -1.993 -2.085<br />

(1.62) (1.62) (-0.59) (-0.61)<br />

Change in Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets 11.001** 11.002** 21.459*** 21.389***<br />

(2.07) (2.08) (4.73) (4.72)<br />

Change in Dividend Yield -6.019 -6.248 0.004 0.004*<br />

(-1.19) (-1.23) (1.58) (1.66)<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> 0.010 0.009 0.017** 0.016**<br />

(1.28) (1.16) (2.18) (2.02)<br />

Intercept 0.593 1.662* -1.098 0.127<br />

(0.62) (1.72) (-0.99) (0.12)<br />

Observations 1195 1195 1175 1175<br />

Adjusted R 2 0.250 0.251 0.251 0.252<br />

Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

43


Table V<br />

Heckman Two-Step Model <strong>of</strong> the Propensity to Make Diversifying Acquisitions in Firms with Above<br />

Median Investment Opportunities<br />

The dependent variable in the first step is an indicator variable that is equal to one if the firm makes an acquisition in a given year. First stage step<br />

regresions are reported as Table I in Appendix A. The dependent variable in the second step is an indicator variable equal to one if the acquirer <strong>and</strong> the<br />

target do not share the same two-digit SIC <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. Results from the second step are presented below. Oldest <strong>CEO</strong> is an indicator variable that<br />

equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong>'s age is in top third <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year, <strong>and</strong> equals zero otherwise. <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> is the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>. Industry MB is the<br />

median market-to-book ratio <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Industry Factor<br />

Score is the median Factor Score <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Factor<br />

Score is a common factor extracted from a firm's investment intensity, market-to-book value <strong>of</strong> assets, R&D expenditures, <strong>and</strong> growth rate <strong>of</strong> market value<br />

<strong>of</strong> assets (Baber, Janakiraman, <strong>and</strong> Kang (1996). Tenure is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the <strong>CEO</strong> has been <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm. Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets equals<br />

(market value equity + book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities). R&D Expense equals R&D expenses scaled by total assets. Market<br />

Leverage equals (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) / (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities + market value <strong>of</strong><br />

common shares). Stock Run Up is the cumulative abnormal return using Carhart's four factor model during the period (-210,-11) prior to the announcement<br />

day. Relative Deal Size is the deal value divided by the acquirers market value <strong>of</strong> equity on the 11 th trading day prior to the announcement day. Public<br />

Target is an indicator variable equal to one if the target is a public firm <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. Private Target is an indicator variable equal to one if the target<br />

is a private firm <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. All Cash Deal is an indicator variable equal to one if the deal was purely financed with cash <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. Stock<br />

Deal is an indicator variable equal to one if the deal was at least partially financed with stock <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. Firm <strong>Age</strong> is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the<br />

firm has been publicly trading. The Inverse Mills Ratio is from the first step <strong>of</strong> the Heckman Two-Step procedure. Industry fixed effects are measured<br />

using the Fama <strong>and</strong> French 12 industry breakdown. T-statistics are presented in parentheses. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, <strong>and</strong> 1%<br />

levels respectively.<br />

Investment Opportunity Proxy<br />

High Industry Market-to-Book High Industry Factor Score<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> 0.068** 0.053*<br />

(2.28) (1.90)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> 0.004** 0.005**<br />

(2.27) (2.54)<br />

Industry MB -0.000 0.001<br />

(-0.01) (0.05)<br />

Industry Factor Score 0.090** 0.090**<br />

(2.37) (2.38)<br />

Log Tenure -0.014 -0.016 -0.020 -0.025<br />

(-0.81) (-0.94) (-1.20) (-1.51)<br />

Log Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets -0.037*** -0.038*** -0.043*** -0.043***<br />

(-3.27) (-3.31) (-3.99) (-4.00)<br />

R&D Expenses 0.007** 0.007*** 0.005** 0.006**<br />

(2.55) (2.60) (1.97) (2.08)<br />

Market Leverage 0.525*** 0.529*** 0.426*** 0.426***<br />

(4.61) (4.65) (3.75) (3.76)<br />

Stock Run Up -0.068*** -0.066*** -0.089*** -0.087***<br />

(-2.75) (-2.65) (-3.60) (-3.50)<br />

Relative Deal Size -0.075* -0.075* -0.090* -0.090*<br />

(-1.75) (-1.76) (-1.93) (-1.91)<br />

Public Target 0.001 -0.000 0.000 -0.002<br />

(0.04) (-0.01) (0.00) (-0.07)<br />

Private Target 0.034 0.035 0.035 0.036<br />

(1.36) (1.40) (1.41) (1.45)<br />

All Cash Deal 0.001 0.002 0.006 0.007<br />

(0.06) (0.08) (0.26) (0.28)<br />

Stock Deal -0.023 -0.019 -0.030 -0.026<br />

(-0.78) (-0.66) (-1.01) (-0.89)<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> 0.004*** 0.003*** 0.004*** 0.004***<br />

(4.29) (4.16) (4.98) (4.74)<br />

Intercept 1.246*** 1.034*** 1.207*** 0.996***<br />

(4.54) (3.78) (4.67) (3.91)<br />

Inverse Mills Ratio -0.601*** -0.605*** -0.538*** -0.546***<br />

(-4.44) (-4.45) (-4.03) (-4.06)<br />

Observations 7270 7270 7301 7301<br />

Pseudo R 2 0.071 0.070 0.097 0.097<br />

Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

44


Table VI<br />

Tobit Regression <strong>of</strong> the Relation between Firm Diversification <strong>and</strong> the <strong>Age</strong> <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong> in Firms with Above Median Investment Opportunities<br />

In Models 1, 2, 5, <strong>and</strong> 6 the dependent variable is the number <strong>of</strong> business segments that the firm operates in. In Models 3, 4, 7, <strong>and</strong> 8 the dependent variable is a Herfindahl Index constructed from the percentage <strong>of</strong><br />

business segment sales in each firm <strong>and</strong> is defined as the sum <strong>of</strong> the square <strong>of</strong> segment sales divided by the square <strong>of</strong> firm sales. The coefficient estimates represent marginal effects. Oldest <strong>CEO</strong> is an indicator variable that<br />

equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong>'s age is in the top third <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> is the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>. Industry MB is the median market-to-book ratio <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given<br />

year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Industry Factor Score is the median Factor Score <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level.<br />

Factor Score is a common factor extracted from a firm's investment intensity, market-to-book value <strong>of</strong> assets, R&D expenditures, <strong>and</strong> growth rate <strong>of</strong> market value <strong>of</strong> assets (Baber, Janakiraman, <strong>and</strong> Kang (1996). Portfolio<br />

Delta is a thous<strong>and</strong> dollar change in <strong>CEO</strong> wealth given a 1% change in stock price. Tenure is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the <strong>CEO</strong> has been <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm. Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets equals (market value equity + book value <strong>of</strong><br />

long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) <strong>and</strong> is in millions. Cash Holding equals (book value <strong>of</strong> cash <strong>and</strong> short-term investments) / total assets. Market Leverage equals (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current<br />

liabilities) / (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities + market value <strong>of</strong> common shares). Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets equals (EBITDA + R&D expenses + advertising expenses) / total assets.<br />

Dividend Yield is the average dividend yield over the current year <strong>and</strong> the previous two years. Founder is an indicator variable that equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong> was <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm when the firm first began trading <strong>and</strong> zero<br />

otherwise. Firm <strong>Age</strong> is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the firm has been publicly trading. Industry fixed effects are measured using the Fama <strong>and</strong> French 12 industry breakdown. St<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered by firm. T-statistics<br />

are presented in parentheses. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, <strong>and</strong> 1% levels respectively.<br />

Firms with Above Median Investment Opportunities Using Industry Market-to-Book Firms with Above Median Investment Opportunities Using Industry Factor Score<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> Segments HHI <strong>of</strong> Business Segments Number <strong>of</strong> Segments HHI <strong>of</strong> Business Segments<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> 0.201** -0.044** 0.220** -0.049**<br />

(1.98) (-2.04) (2.17) (-2.27)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> 0.021** -0.005*** 0.021*** -0.005***<br />

(2.49) (-2.80) (2.63) (-2.82)<br />

Industry MB 0.076 0.078 -0.023 -0.023<br />

(1.02) (1.05) (-1.46) (-1.50)<br />

Industry Factor Score 0.223 0.220 -0.063* -0.063*<br />

(1.20) (1.18) (-1.73) (-1.71)<br />

Log 1+Portfolio Delta 0.074 0.083 -0.016 -0.018 0.074 0.082 -0.015 -0.017<br />

(1.30) (1.44) (-1.34) (-1.51) (1.32) (1.44) (-1.32) (-1.46)<br />

Log Tenure -0.095 -0.130* 0.020 0.029* -0.104 -0.139* 0.017 0.025<br />

(-1.29) (-1.69) (1.34) (1.84) (-1.44) (-1.85) (1.15) (1.63)<br />

Log Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets 0.194*** 0.187*** -0.022* -0.021* 0.198*** 0.192*** -0.023** -0.022*<br />

(3.25) (3.13) (-1.89) (-1.74) (3.33) (3.23) (-1.98) (-1.86)<br />

Cash Holdings -2.654*** -2.611*** 0.651*** 0.640*** -2.801*** -2.751*** 0.693*** 0.681***<br />

(-7.74) (-7.59) (9.17) (8.99) (-7.97) (-7.81) (9.68) (9.49)<br />

Market Leverage 0.582* 0.580* -0.124* -0.123* 0.402 0.406 -0.073 -0.074<br />

(1.73) (1.72) (-1.75) (-1.74) (1.23) (1.24) (-1.07) (-1.09)<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets -2.044*** -2.040*** 0.444*** 0.442*** -1.947*** -1.939*** 0.411*** 0.409***<br />

(-4.08) (-4.07) (4.30) (4.28) (-3.88) (-3.86) (3.98) (3.96)<br />

Dividend Yield 18.077*** 18.042*** -3.340*** -3.329*** 16.764*** 16.642*** -2.860*** -2.830***<br />

(3.51) (3.51) (-3.32) (-3.32) (3.26) (3.24) (-2.87) (-2.84)<br />

Founder <strong>CEO</strong> -0.091 -0.099 0.006 0.007 -0.064 -0.070 0.002 0.004<br />

(-0.47) (-0.50) (0.14) (0.19) (-0.33) (-0.37) (0.06) (0.10)<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> 0.026*** 0.025*** -0.005*** -0.005*** 0.028*** 0.027*** -0.006*** -0.005***<br />

(6.64) (6.45) (-6.94) (-6.70) (7.38) (7.21) (-8.18) (-7.95)<br />

Intercept -1.756*** -1.644*** 1.384*** 1.357*** -1.369*** -1.224** 1.288*** 1.255***<br />

(-3.38) (-3.14) (13.38) (13.06) (-2.66) (-2.35) (12.92) (12.45)<br />

Observations 6411 6411 6411 6411 6469 6469 6469 6469<br />

Pseudo R 2 0.102 0.103 0.208 0.210 0.114 0.115 0.235 0.237<br />

Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

45


Table VII<br />

The Relation between <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> <strong>and</strong> Stock Market Performance<br />

In Panel A, I construct a long portfolio that consists <strong>of</strong> equal weighted returns <strong>of</strong> all firms that have a younger <strong>CEO</strong>,<br />

where a younger <strong>CEO</strong> is defined as a <strong>CEO</strong> whose age is in the bottom tercile <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year. I then<br />

construct a short portfolio that consists <strong>of</strong> equal weighted returns <strong>of</strong> all firms that have an older <strong>CEO</strong>, where an older<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> is defined as a <strong>CEO</strong> whose age is in the top tercile <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year. Each month, I subtract the return<br />

on the short portfolio from the return on the long portfolio. Following Carhart (1997), I examine portfolio returns in<br />

excess <strong>of</strong> the four-factor model. I regress the differences in returns between the two portfolios on the CRSP valueweighted<br />

market return less the risk-free rate, SMB (small minus big), HML (high minus low), <strong>and</strong> MOM (momentum).<br />

SMB, HML, <strong>and</strong> MOM are the returns on zero-investment factor-mimicking portfolios designed to capture size, bookto-market,<br />

<strong>and</strong> momentum effects, respectively. Alpha is the abnormal return in excess <strong>of</strong> passive investment in the<br />

factors. Factor returns are from Kenneth R. French's website. In Panel B, I apply the same methodology but with<br />

different portfolios. In Panel B, I restrict the sample to firms managed by older <strong>CEO</strong>s <strong>and</strong> partition the sample into firms<br />

with above median growth opportunities <strong>and</strong> firms with below median growth opportunities, as approximated by the<br />

firm’s industry market-to-book. For each group <strong>of</strong> firms, I construct a long portfolio that consists <strong>of</strong> equal weighted<br />

returns <strong>of</strong> firms that have a positive investment residual <strong>and</strong> a short portfolio that consists <strong>of</strong> equal weighted returns<br />

<strong>of</strong> firms that have a negative investment residual. I calculate a firm's investment residual by regressing the firm's<br />

investment in R&D + CAPEX on the firm's Market-to-Book ratio, logarithm <strong>of</strong> Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets, Cash Holdings,<br />

Market Leverage, Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>itability, Dividend Yield, Firm <strong>Age</strong>, year fixed effects, <strong>and</strong> Fama <strong>and</strong> French 12<br />

industries. Firms with a negative residual are then classified as firms with negative investment residuals, <strong>and</strong> firms with<br />

a positive residual are classified as firms with positive investment residuals. St<strong>and</strong>ard Errors are White Robust<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard Errors. T-statistics are presented in parentheses. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, <strong>and</strong> 1%<br />

levels respectively.<br />

Panel A: Excess stock returns from taking a long position in portfolios consisting <strong>of</strong> younger <strong>CEO</strong>s <strong>and</strong> a short<br />

position in portfolios consisting <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s<br />

Alpha RMRF SMB HML MOM Adj. R 2<br />

Estimate 0.500*** 0.078** 0.226*** -0.334*** -0.048* 0.604 204<br />

t-Statistic (4.69) (2.27) (6.38) (-7.77) (-1.85)<br />

Panel B: Excess stock returns from taking a long position in portfolios consisting <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s who have a<br />

positive investment residual <strong>and</strong> a short position in portfolios consisting <strong>of</strong> older <strong>CEO</strong>s who have a negative<br />

investment residual (underinvest)<br />

Firms with above median growth opportunities<br />

Alpha RMRF SMB HML MOM Adj. R 2<br />

Estimate 0.377* 0.180*** 0.099 -0.225*** -0.035 0.220 204<br />

t-Statistic (1.79) (3.24) (1.33) (-2.93) (-0.55)<br />

Firms with below median growth opportunities<br />

Alpha RMRF SMB HML MOM Adj. R 2<br />

Estimate -0.022 -0.038 0.016 -0.056 -0.034 0.014 204<br />

t-Statistic (-0.15) (-1.05) (0.31) (-1.07) (-0.88)<br />

Obs.<br />

Obs.<br />

Obs.<br />

46


Table VIII<br />

The Relation between <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong>, Sales Growth, <strong>and</strong> Income Growth<br />

In Models 1, 2, 3, <strong>and</strong> 4, the dependent variable is the firm's industry adjusted sales growth over the next three years. In Models 5, 6, 7, <strong>and</strong> 8, the dependent variable is the firm's industry adjusted growth in operating income before<br />

depreciation over the next three years. Both growth measures are industry adjusted by subtracting the median growth rate <strong>of</strong> the corresponding three-digit SIC industry. Investment Activity is (capital expenditures + R&D expenses) / total<br />

assets. Oldest <strong>CEO</strong> is an indicator variable that equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong>'s age is in top third <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> is the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>. Industry Market-to-Book is the median market-to-book ratio <strong>of</strong> a<br />

firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Industry Factor Score is the median Factor Score <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at<br />

the three-digit SIC level. Factor Score is a common factor extracted from a firm's investment intensity, market-to-book value <strong>of</strong> assets, R&D expenditures, <strong>and</strong> growth rate <strong>of</strong> market value <strong>of</strong> assets (Baber, Janakiraman, <strong>and</strong> Kang (1996).<br />

Portfolio Delta is a thous<strong>and</strong> dollar change in <strong>CEO</strong> wealth given a 1% change in stock price. Tenure is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the <strong>CEO</strong> has been <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm. Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets equals (market value equity + book value <strong>of</strong> longterm<br />

debt + debt in current liabilities) <strong>and</strong> is in millions. Firm Market-to-Book equals (book value <strong>of</strong> assets + the market value <strong>of</strong> equity - the book value <strong>of</strong> equity - balance sheet deferred taxes) / total assets. Cash Holding equals (book<br />

value <strong>of</strong> cash <strong>and</strong> short-term investments) / total assets. Market Leverage equals (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) / (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities + market value <strong>of</strong> common shares).Pre-<br />

Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets equals (EBITDA + R&D expenses + advertising expenses) / total assets. Dividend Yield is the average dividend yield over the current year <strong>and</strong> the previous two years. Founder is an indicator variable<br />

that equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong> was <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm when the firm first began trading <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. Firm <strong>Age</strong> is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the firm has been publicly trading. Industry fixed effects are measured using the Fama <strong>and</strong> French 12<br />

industry breakdown. St<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered by firm. T-statistics are presented in parentheses. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, <strong>and</strong> 1% levels respectively.<br />

Three-Year Growth in Sales<br />

Three-Year Growth in Operating Income<br />

High Industry Market-to-Book High Industry Factor Score High Industry Market-to-Book High Industry Factor Score<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> -6.052** -4.263 -10.463** -8.143*<br />

(-2.21) (-1.50) (-2.46) (-1.94)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> -0.535** -0.518** -0.715** -0.648**<br />

(-2.52) (-2.33) (-2.28) (-2.05)<br />

Industry MB 1.855 1.775 -0.831 -0.930<br />

(0.93) (0.89) (-0.24) (-0.27)<br />

Industry Factor Score -1.607 -1.471 -0.630 -0.445<br />

(-0.37) (-0.34) (-0.10) (-0.07)<br />

Investment Activity 1.616*** 1.597*** 1.617*** 1.592*** 0.147 0.129 0.228 0.207<br />

(8.69) (8.57) (8.58) (8.43) (0.63) (0.55) (0.94) (0.86)<br />

Log 1+Portfolio Delta 10.061*** 9.878*** 11.014*** 10.849*** 4.885** 4.676* 6.515** 6.343**<br />

(6.41) (6.30) (6.79) (6.71) (1.98) (1.88) (2.50) (2.42)<br />

Log Tenure -2.468 -1.653 -2.824 -1.782 -0.448 0.231 -0.676 0.154<br />

(-1.25) (-0.81) (-1.43) (-0.87) (-0.17) (0.08) (-0.24) (0.05)<br />

Log Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets 1.663 1.816 1.097 1.233 7.258*** 7.425*** 6.099*** 6.241***<br />

(1.24) (1.36) (0.80) (0.90) (3.38) (3.45) (2.69) (2.75)<br />

Cash Holdings 34.626*** 33.864*** 29.612*** 28.550*** -12.399 -13.046 -22.994 -23.984*<br />

(3.53) (3.43) (3.10) (2.97) (-0.86) (-0.90) (-1.59) (-1.66)<br />

Market Leverage -39.345*** -39.174*** -29.080*** -28.995*** -23.352* -23.075* -25.179* -25.063*<br />

(-4.45) (-4.44) (-3.27) (-3.27) (-1.67) (-1.65) (-1.75) (-1.75)<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets -116.194*** -115.854*** -112.580*** -112.341*** 26.120 26.767 29.430 29.823<br />

(-7.24) (-7.22) (-6.87) (-6.85) (1.24) (1.28) (1.37) (1.39)<br />

Dividend Yield -327.608*** -327.234*** -334.520** -331.671** -986.040*** -988.550*** -929.344*** -929.212***<br />

(-2.66) (-2.66) (-2.55) (-2.54) (-5.66) (-5.66) (-5.13) (-5.12)<br />

Founder <strong>CEO</strong> 6.727 6.793 5.998 6.062 7.239 7.294 3.299 3.336<br />

(1.36) (1.37) (1.17) (1.18) (0.97) (0.97) (0.44) (0.44)<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> -0.685*** -0.669*** -0.686*** -0.668*** -0.539*** -0.523*** -0.502*** -0.487***<br />

(-7.81) (-7.61) (-7.86) (-7.63) (-4.49) (-4.34) (-4.20) (-4.06)<br />

Intercept -3.958 22.370 6.967 31.655** -23.291 12.110 -28.984* 2.236<br />

(-0.35) (1.46) (0.59) (1.98) (-1.40) (0.53) (-1.74) (0.10)<br />

Observations 6102 6102 6118 6118 5962 5962 5959 5959<br />

Adjusted R 2 0.181 0.182 0.174 0.175 0.040 0.040 0.040 0.041<br />

Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

47


Table IX<br />

The Relation between the <strong>Age</strong> <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>, Performance Sensitive Compensation, <strong>and</strong> Investment<br />

Activity in Firms with Above Median Investment Opportunities<br />

The dependent variable is measured in time period t, whereas the independent variables are measured in time period t-1. The dependent variable is Investment<br />

Activity. Investment Activity is (capital expenditures + R&D expenses) / total assets. Oldest <strong>CEO</strong> is an indicator variable that equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong>'s age is in<br />

the top third <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> is the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>. New Delta is the sum <strong>of</strong> the Delta from new stock <strong>and</strong> option<br />

awards <strong>and</strong> represents a thous<strong>and</strong> dollar change in <strong>CEO</strong> compensation given a 1% change in stock price. Industry Market-to-Book is the median market-tobook<br />

ratio <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Industry Factor Score is the median<br />

Factor Score <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Factor Score is a common factor<br />

extracted from a firm's investment intensity, market-to-book value <strong>of</strong> assets, R&D expenditures, <strong>and</strong> growth rate <strong>of</strong> market value <strong>of</strong> assets (Baber, Janakiraman,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Kang (1996). Portfolio Delta is a thous<strong>and</strong> dollar change in <strong>CEO</strong> wealth given a 1% change in stock price. Tenure is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the <strong>CEO</strong> has<br />

been <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm. Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets equals (market value equity + book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) <strong>and</strong> is in millions. Firm<br />

Market-to-Book equals (book value <strong>of</strong> assets + the market value <strong>of</strong> equity - the book value <strong>of</strong> equity - balance sheet deferred taxes) / total assets. Cash Holding<br />

equals (book value <strong>of</strong> cash <strong>and</strong> short-term investments) / total assets. Market Leverage equals (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) / (book<br />

value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities + market value <strong>of</strong> common shares). Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets equals (EBITDA + R&D expenses +<br />

advertising expenses) / total assets. Dividend Yield is the average dividend yield over the current year <strong>and</strong> the previous two years. Founder is an indicator<br />

variable that equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong> was <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm when the firm first began trading <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. Firm <strong>Age</strong> is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the firm has<br />

been publicly trading. Industry fixed effects are measured using the Fama <strong>and</strong> French 12 industry breakdown. St<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered by firm. T-statistics<br />

are presented in parentheses. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, <strong>and</strong> 1% levels respectively.<br />

High Industry Market-to-Book<br />

Investment Opportunity Proxy<br />

High Industry Factor Score<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> -0.680* -0.629<br />

(-1.66) (-1.56)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> -0.065** -0.070**<br />

(-2.00) (-2.17)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> * Log 1+New Delta -0.176 -0.077<br />

(-1.07) (-0.46)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> * Log 1+New Delta -0.016 -0.012<br />

(-1.43) (-1.04)<br />

Log 1+New Delta 0.403*** 0.338*** 0.375*** 0.341***<br />

(3.56) (3.71) (3.33) (3.73)<br />

Industry MB 0.488 0.483<br />

(1.44) (1.44)<br />

Industry Factor Score 3.627*** 3.639***<br />

(5.18) (5.19)<br />

Log Lagged Portfolio Delta -0.546*** -0.556*** -0.571*** -0.583***<br />

(-2.64) (-2.69) (-2.77) (-2.83)<br />

Log Tenure+1 0.460 0.557 0.316 0.444<br />

(1.21) (1.40) (0.87) (1.15)<br />

Log Market value <strong>of</strong> Assets -0.243 -0.225 -0.231 -0.212<br />

(-1.28) (-1.18) (-1.18) (-1.08)<br />

Cash Holdings 14.829*** 14.703*** 13.244*** 13.088***<br />

(8.55) (8.45) (8.48) (8.34)<br />

Market Leverage -2.358 -2.384 -2.144 -2.156<br />

(-1.42) (-1.43) (-1.48) (-1.48)<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets 22.428*** 22.344*** 22.986*** 22.894***<br />

(9.92) (9.91) (10.12) (10.10)<br />

Dividend Yield -126.051*** -125.321*** -128.205*** -127.154***<br />

(-6.20) (-6.20) (-5.98) (-5.95)<br />

Founder <strong>CEO</strong> -0.908 -0.891 -0.950 -0.936<br />

(-1.24) (-1.22) (-1.34) (-1.32)<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> -0.008 -0.005 -0.021* -0.019<br />

(-0.62) (-0.44) (-1.78) (-1.57)<br />

Intercept 9.359*** 8.943*** 11.358*** 10.815***<br />

(5.13) (4.83) (5.97) (5.59)<br />

Observations 5169 5169 5185 5185<br />

Adjusted R 2 0.383 0.383 0.387 0.388<br />

Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

48


Table X<br />

Tobit Regression <strong>of</strong> the Relation between <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Delta <strong>of</strong> New Equity Awards in Firms<br />

with Above Median Investment Opportunities<br />

The dependent variable is measured in time period t, whereas the independent variables are measured in time period t-1. The dependent variable is the<br />

logarithm <strong>of</strong> one plus the Delta <strong>of</strong> new equity awards, where the Delta <strong>of</strong> new equity awards is the sum <strong>of</strong> the Delta from option awards <strong>and</strong> the Delta <strong>of</strong><br />

stock awards. Delta represents a thous<strong>and</strong> dollar change in <strong>CEO</strong> compensation given a 1% change in stock price. The coefficient estimates represent<br />

marginal effects. Oldest <strong>CEO</strong> is an indicator variable that equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong>'s age is in the top third <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise.<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> is the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>. Industry Market-to-Book is the median market-to-book ratio <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an<br />

industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Industry Factor Score is the median Factor Score <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given year,<br />

where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Factor Score is a common factor extracted from a firm's investment intensity, market-to-book<br />

value <strong>of</strong> assets, R&D expenditures, <strong>and</strong> growth rate <strong>of</strong> market value <strong>of</strong> assets (Baber, Janakiraman, <strong>and</strong> Kang (1996). Portfolio Delta is a thous<strong>and</strong> dollar<br />

change in <strong>CEO</strong> wealth given a 1% change in stock price. Tenure is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the <strong>CEO</strong> has been <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm. Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets<br />

equals (market value equity + book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) <strong>and</strong> is in millions. Firm Market-to-Book equals (book value <strong>of</strong><br />

assets + the market value <strong>of</strong> equity - the book value <strong>of</strong> equity - balance sheet deferred taxes) / total assets. Cash Holding equals (book value <strong>of</strong> cash <strong>and</strong><br />

short-term investments) / total assets. Market Leverage equals (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) / (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt<br />

+ debt in current liabilities + market value <strong>of</strong> common shares). Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets equals (EBITDA + R&D expenses + advertising<br />

expenses) / total assets. Dividend Yield is the average dividend yield over the current year <strong>and</strong> the previous two years. Founder is an indicator variable<br />

that equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong> was <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm when the firm first began trading <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. Firm <strong>Age</strong> is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the firm has<br />

been publicly trading. Industry fixed effects are measured using the Fama <strong>and</strong> French 12 industry breakdown. St<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered by firm. Tstatistics<br />

are presented in parentheses. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, <strong>and</strong> 1% levels respectively.<br />

Investment Opportunity Proxy<br />

High Industry Market-to-Book High Industry Factor Score<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> -0.137*** -0.147***<br />

(-3.24) (-3.77)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> -0.014*** -0.014***<br />

(-4.69) (-4.87)<br />

Industry MB 0.024 0.022<br />

(0.80) (0.74)<br />

Industry Factor Score -0.019 -0.014<br />

(-0.32) (-0.24)<br />

Investments 0.003* 0.003 0.004** 0.003*<br />

(1.80) (1.56) (2.12) (1.84)<br />

Log 1+Portfolio Delta 0.216*** 0.211*** 0.214*** 0.208***<br />

(8.40) (8.28) (8.60) (8.47)<br />

Log Tenure -0.105*** -0.082*** -0.096*** -0.073***<br />

(-3.76) (-2.86) (-3.55) (-2.63)<br />

Log Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets 0.425*** 0.429*** 0.424*** 0.428***<br />

(19.57) (19.91) (20.35) (20.71)<br />

Cash Holdings 0.390*** 0.369*** 0.428*** 0.405***<br />

(3.46) (3.28) (3.88) (3.66)<br />

Market Leverage 0.099 0.100 0.045 0.047<br />

(0.72) (0.74) (0.35) (0.37)<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets 0.430*** 0.432*** 0.322** 0.328**<br />

(2.69) (2.71) (2.01) (2.06)<br />

Dividend Yield -5.993** -5.883** -4.709** -4.635**<br />

(-2.48) (-2.42) (-2.15) (-2.11)<br />

Founder <strong>CEO</strong> 0.043 0.046 0.033 0.036<br />

(0.64) (0.70) (0.49) (0.54)<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.002*<br />

(0.41) (0.67) (1.63) (1.90)<br />

Intercept -4.594*** -4.671*** -4.605*** -4.695***<br />

(-23.42) (-23.66) (-23.43) (-23.77)<br />

Observations 6280 6280 6299 6299<br />

Pseudo R 2 0.196 0.197 0.202 0.203<br />

Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

49


Table XI<br />

The Relation between <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> <strong>and</strong> Annual Cash Salary in Firms with Above Median<br />

Investment Opportunities<br />

The dependent variable is measured in time period t, whereas the independent variables are measured in time period t-1. The dependent variable<br />

is the logarithm <strong>of</strong> one plus the <strong>CEO</strong>'s annual salary. Oldest <strong>CEO</strong> is an indicator variable that equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong>'s age is in the top third <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> is the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>. Industry Market-to-Book is the median market-to-book ratio <strong>of</strong> a<br />

firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Industry Factor Score is the median<br />

Factor Score <strong>of</strong> a firm's corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Factor Score is a<br />

common factor extracted from a firm's investment intensity, market-to-book value <strong>of</strong> assets, R&D expenditures, <strong>and</strong> growth rate <strong>of</strong> market value<br />

<strong>of</strong> assets (Baber, Janakiraman, <strong>and</strong> Kang (1996). Portfolio Delta is a thous<strong>and</strong> dollar change in <strong>CEO</strong> wealth given a 1% change in stock price.<br />

Tenure is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the <strong>CEO</strong> has been <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm. Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets equals (market value equity + book value <strong>of</strong> longterm<br />

debt + debt in current liabilities) <strong>and</strong> is in millions. Firm Market-to-Book equals (book value <strong>of</strong> assets + the market value <strong>of</strong> equity - the<br />

book value <strong>of</strong> equity - balance sheet deferred taxes) / total assets. Cash Holding equals (book value <strong>of</strong> cash <strong>and</strong> short-term investments) / total<br />

assets. Market Leverage equals (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities) / (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current<br />

liabilities + market value <strong>of</strong> common shares). Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets equals (EBITDA + R&D expenses + advertising expenses) /<br />

total assets. Dividend Yield is the average dividend yield over the current year <strong>and</strong> the previous two years. Founder is an indicator variable that<br />

equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong> was <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm when the firm first began trading <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. Firm <strong>Age</strong> is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the firm<br />

has been publicly trading. Industry fixed effects are measured using the Fama <strong>and</strong> French 12 industry breakdown. St<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered<br />

by firm. T-statistics are presented in parentheses. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, <strong>and</strong> 1% levels respectively.<br />

Investment Opportunity Proxy<br />

High Industry Market-to-Book High Industry Factor Score<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> 0.052*** 0.050***<br />

(2.72) (2.79)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> 0.006*** 0.005***<br />

(3.75) (3.71)<br />

Industry MB 0.024** 0.025**<br />

(2.31) (2.40)<br />

Industry Factor Score 0.069*** 0.067***<br />

(2.89) (2.81)<br />

Investments -0.004*** -0.004*** -0.004*** -0.004***<br />

(-4.32) (-4.12) (-4.33) (-4.10)<br />

Log 1+Portfolio Delta 0.027*** 0.029*** 0.028** 0.029***<br />

(2.61) (2.84) (2.54) (2.71)<br />

Log Tenure -0.015 -0.025* -0.013 -0.022<br />

(-1.05) (-1.69) (-0.98) (-1.62)<br />

Log Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets 0.141*** 0.140*** 0.142*** 0.141***<br />

(11.49) (11.37) (11.28) (11.17)<br />

Cash Holdings -0.292*** -0.284*** -0.334*** -0.324***<br />

(-4.37) (-4.24) (-5.04) (-4.90)<br />

Market Leverage 0.347*** 0.346*** 0.339*** 0.339***<br />

(5.88) (5.86) (5.91) (5.91)<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets 0.118 0.118 0.050 0.049<br />

(1.57) (1.57) (0.66) (0.66)<br />

Dividend Yield 0.806 0.769 0.940 0.905<br />

(0.99) (0.95) (1.17) (1.13)<br />

Founder <strong>CEO</strong> 0.010 0.009 0.005 0.005<br />

(0.30) (0.27) (0.16) (0.15)<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> 0.004*** 0.004*** 0.004*** 0.004***<br />

(6.85) (6.57) (7.32) (7.08)<br />

Intercept 5.251*** 5.282*** 5.349*** 5.385***<br />

(62.69) (62.10) (59.94) (58.77)<br />

Observations 6727 6727 6740 6740<br />

Adjusted R 2 0.505 0.508 0.521 0.524<br />

Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

50


Appendix A<br />

Table I<br />

First Step <strong>of</strong> Heckman Two-Step Model <strong>of</strong> the Propensity to Make Diversifying Acquisitions in Firms<br />

with Above Median Investment Opportunities<br />

The dependent variable in the first step is an indicator variable that is equal to one if the firm makes an acquisition in a given year. First stage step regresions<br />

are reported here. The dependent variable in the second step is an indicator variable equal to one if the acquirer <strong>and</strong> the target do not share the same two-digit<br />

SIC <strong>and</strong> zero otherwise. Results from the second step are presented in Table V. Oldest <strong>CEO</strong> is an indicator variable that equals one if the <strong>CEO</strong>'s age is in top<br />

third <strong>of</strong> <strong>CEO</strong> ages in a given year, <strong>and</strong> equals zero otherwise. <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> is the age <strong>of</strong> the <strong>CEO</strong>. Industry MB is the median market-to-book ratio <strong>of</strong> a firm's<br />

corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Industry Factor Score is the median Factor Score <strong>of</strong> a firm's<br />

corresponding industry in a given year, where an industry is measured at the three-digit SIC level. Factor Score is a common factor extracted from a firm's<br />

investment intensity, market-to-book value <strong>of</strong> assets, R&D expenditures, <strong>and</strong> growth rate <strong>of</strong> market value <strong>of</strong> assets (Baber, Janakiraman, <strong>and</strong> Kang (1996).<br />

Tenure is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the <strong>CEO</strong> has been <strong>CEO</strong> <strong>of</strong> the firm. Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets equals (market value equity + book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt +<br />

debt in current liabilities). R&D Expense equals R&D expenses scaled by total assets. Market Leverage equals (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current<br />

liabilities) / (book value <strong>of</strong> long-term debt + debt in current liabilities + market value <strong>of</strong> common shares). Cash Holding equals (book value <strong>of</strong> cash <strong>and</strong> shortterm<br />

investments) / total assets. Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets equals (EBITDA + R&D expenses + advertising expenses) / total assets. Propert, Plant,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Equipement is property, plant, <strong>and</strong> equipement / total assets. Dividend Yield is the average dividend yield over the current year <strong>and</strong> the previous two<br />

years. Firm <strong>Age</strong> is the number <strong>of</strong> years that the firm has been publicly trading. Industry fixed effects are measured using the Fama <strong>and</strong> French 12 industry<br />

breakdown. T-statistics are presented in parentheses. *, **, *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, <strong>and</strong> 1% levels respectively.<br />

High Industry Market-to-Book<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

Older <strong>CEO</strong> -0.044 -0.029<br />

(-1.15) (-0.79)<br />

<strong>CEO</strong> <strong>Age</strong> -0.004 -0.004*<br />

(-1.50) (-1.74)<br />

Log Tenure -0.013 -0.008 -0.015 -0.006<br />

(-0.59) (-0.36) (-0.67) (-0.26)<br />

Log Market Value <strong>of</strong> Assets 0.058*** 0.058*** 0.056*** 0.056***<br />

Industry MB -0.034 -0.035<br />

(4.78) (4.78) (4.69) (4.68)<br />

(-1.13) (-1.11)<br />

Investment Opportunity Proxy<br />

High Industry Factor Score<br />

Industry Factor Score -0.093* -0.092*<br />

(-1.82) (-1.79)<br />

R&D Expenses -0.015*** -0.015*** -0.017*** -0.017***<br />

(-5.57) (-5.60) (-6.01) (-6.06)<br />

Market Leverage -0.473*** -0.471*** -0.587*** -0.584***<br />

(-3.51) (-3.50) (-4.53) (-4.50)<br />

Cash Holdings -0.399*** -0.406*** -0.344*** -0.356***<br />

(-3.72) (-3.77) (-3.26) (-3.36)<br />

Pre-Investment Pr<strong>of</strong>its / Book Assets 0.029 0.029 0.074 0.071<br />

(0.18) (0.18) (0.45) (0.44)<br />

Property, Plant, <strong>and</strong> Equipement -0.435*** -0.433*** -0.411*** -0.408***<br />

(-6.96) (-6.91) (-6.51) (-6.46)<br />

Dividend Yield -3.278* -3.217* -5.839*** -5.737***<br />

(-1.76) (-1.73) (-3.12) (-3.06)<br />

Firm <strong>Age</strong> -0.001 -0.001 0.000 0.000<br />

(-0.87) (-0.77) (0.20) (0.35)<br />

Intercept -0.892*** -0.709*** -0.822*** -0.621***<br />

(-4.97) (-3.29) (-4.54) (-2.92)<br />

Observations 7270 7270 7301 7301<br />

Pseudo R 2<br />

0.046 0.046 0.041 0.041<br />

Industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

51

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!