05.06.2015 Views

JPI Spring 2015

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Table of Contents<br />

Letter from the Editor | Madeleine Wykstra 1<br />

<strong>JPI</strong> <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> Editorial Board 2<br />

Sexual Citizenship and EU Conditionality | Séhzad M. Sooklall 3<br />

Does Official Development Assistance Contribute to Long- Term Growth and Stability in<br />

Afghanistan? | David Esmati 22<br />

From Operation Serval to Barkhane: Understanding France’s Increased Involvement in Africa<br />

in the Context of Françafrique and Post- colonialism | Carmen Cuesta Roca 32<br />

China’s Economic Espionage: Stealing, not Destroying | Reema Hibrawi 41<br />

The Anti-Communist Myth: A Critical Examination of Aggregate U.S. Foreign Policy<br />

Analysis of the Cold War | Dylan Heyden 48<br />

An Appraisal of the Joint Development Approach to the South China Sea Dispute:<br />

Prospects and Challenges | Guan Hui Lee 56<br />

Is Sustained Economic Growth in Russia’s Future? | Joel Alexander 66<br />

Iraq: State Or National Collapse? | Paul Mutter 79<br />

Power to the Babushkas? Reconsidering the Relationship between Russian Politics<br />

and the Elderly | Ilaria Parogni 90<br />

From Multi-Party to Two-Party System: The Applicability of Duverger’s Law and<br />

the Taiwanese Election Reform | Pei-Yu Wei 101<br />

Empowering Women or Hollow Words? Gender References in Peace Agreements |<br />

Lori Perkovich 111<br />

A New Cold War in the Arttic? | Roma Parhad 123<br />

Faculty Spotlight: A Conversation with Professor Michael Williams |<br />

Interviewed by Jordan Clifford 130


Letter from the Editor | <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

It is with great pleasure that I present the Journal of Political Inquiry’s <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> publication.<br />

This issue is the product of a diverse, talented, and ambitious team of writers and editors. It features<br />

student authors from several different New York University graduate programs. These students<br />

invested commendable time and energy into their respective articles, and that effort shows in the<br />

quality of their work.<br />

The <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> issue, of course, would not have been possible without the valiant efforts of our<br />

managing editors, who worked tirelessly to prepare these articles for publication. The Journal is also<br />

fortunate to have had an exceptional team of students serve on the editorial board this year. In<br />

addition, our operations team should be commended for expanding <strong>JPI</strong>’s readership and<br />

participation to many different programs at GSAS and NYU.<br />

This has been a transformative year for <strong>JPI</strong>. We sought to expand the Journal’s presence and its<br />

substance, and we have succeeded in doing both. As you know, <strong>JPI</strong> is a student-cultivated, studentled<br />

publication. Its success this year was made possible by students who recognize the value in<br />

exchanging ideas, skills, and perspectives outside of the classroom. The Fall 2014 and <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

publications speak to our collective ambition and initiative, and the value we see in producing<br />

something with our peers, for our peers.<br />

In my Fall 2014 letter, I wrote that we must “take advantage of our time together in graduate<br />

school, and the pool of talent that comprises our own student body.” The hundreds of hours spent<br />

in putting together <strong>JPI</strong>’s Fall 2014 and <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> issues have allowed us to do just that, and we<br />

are collectively better for it. Although <strong>JPI</strong> will continue evolving and growing under each new<br />

editorial board, the students who worked so hard to bring new life to <strong>JPI</strong> this year have left their<br />

own indelible mark. I thank them for their dedication—and I thank you, the readers, for your<br />

support of our efforts.<br />

Wishing you all a happy and successful summer,<br />

Madeleine Wykstra<br />

Editor-in-Chief<br />

Madeleine is a second-year MA candidate at New York University. She graduated summa cum laude from the<br />

State University of New York at Purchase, with a BA in political science and a minor in economics.<br />

Previously, Madeleine served as an editor for the Center for Constitutional Transitions at NYU Law School,<br />

and as an editorial intern for the Carnegie Council for Ethics in International Affairs. Her research interests<br />

include multilateral responses to intrastate conflict, the emergence and development of transnational<br />

regulatory standards, and the design of administrative mechanisms to improve natural resource revenue<br />

management in developing countries. She will begin a JD program at Berkeley School of Law in the fall.<br />

1 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 1


Editorial Board<br />

Editor-in- Chief<br />

Madeleine Wykstra<br />

Managing Editors<br />

Jie Zhan<br />

Roma Parhad<br />

Ásdís Ólafsdóttir<br />

Xing Lu<br />

Mireia Triguero Roura<br />

Dylan Heyden<br />

Guan Hui Lee<br />

Hannah Thomas<br />

Ji Min Kiim<br />

Joseph Lavicka<br />

Khobaib Osailan<br />

Marcela Villacob<br />

Editors<br />

Paul Mutter<br />

Pei-Yu Wei<br />

Wenjun Zeng<br />

Won Min Seo<br />

Zehra Rehman<br />

Jordan Clifford<br />

Ramiro Fúnez<br />

Special thanks to our honorary guest editor Elizabeth Bennett<br />

2 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 2


Sexual Citizenship and<br />

EU Conditionality<br />

Can Supranational<br />

Organizations Facilitate the<br />

Advancement of Sexual<br />

Minorities?<br />

The Case of Former Yugoslav<br />

Republics and EU Accession<br />

Séhzad M. Sooklall<br />

Citizenship is transcending traditional<br />

European states’ borders. More<br />

than a half billion Europeans are<br />

now citizens of both the European Union<br />

(EU) and one of the 28 member states. 1<br />

Article 20 of The Treaty on the<br />

Functioning of the European Union states<br />

that “every person holding the nationality<br />

of a Member State shall be a citizen of the<br />

Union” and that “citizenship of the Union<br />

shall be additional to and not replace<br />

national citizenship.” 2 Do the rights and<br />

protections afforded by member states<br />

necessarily mirror the ones afforded at the<br />

supranational level? Is one set of<br />

citizenship rights more desirable than the<br />

other?<br />

Several factors must be considered:<br />

does the citizen in question constitute part<br />

1 Dimitry Kochenov, “The Present and the Future<br />

of EU Citizenship: A Bird’s Eye View of the Legal<br />

Debate,” Jean Monnet Working Papers (NYU Law<br />

School) No.2/12 (2012): 3,<br />

http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2063200.<br />

2 The Member States, “Consolidated version of the<br />

Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union,”<br />

Official Journal of the European Union (2012),<br />

http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/?uri=CELEX:12012E/TXT.<br />

of the minority or majority in terms of the<br />

power structure of that state, and very<br />

importantly, to which member state does<br />

the citizen belong? In the process of EU<br />

enlargement, applicant countries have to<br />

harmonize their national legislation with<br />

the acquis communautaire before entry into<br />

the union. 3 This paper explores whether<br />

conditionality to EU membership has<br />

served as an effective instrument for<br />

positive change in the lives of sexual<br />

minorities in the applicant countries. More<br />

specifically, this paper will focus on the<br />

former Yugoslav republics of Serbia and<br />

Montenegro, which are currently in the<br />

negotiation phase for EU accession, and<br />

Croatia, which was admitted to the union<br />

in July 2013. 4<br />

This paper will begin with the<br />

introduction of relevant context, including<br />

operational definitions. It will be followed<br />

by a review of Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship: EU Accession and the Changing<br />

Position of Sexual Minorities in the Post-Yugoslav<br />

context, by Katja Kahlina. It will then<br />

compare EU accession of the former<br />

Yugoslav republics and the resulting<br />

impact on sexual minorities with recent<br />

events in France in regards to same sex<br />

marriage legalization. This comparative and<br />

interpretive analysis finds that although<br />

advancement of sexual citizenship in<br />

France was not imposed by the European<br />

Union, riots and anti-gay violence still<br />

3 Katja Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship: EU Accession and the Changing<br />

Position of Sexual Minorities in the Post-Yugoslav<br />

Context,” University of Edinburgh School of Law: The<br />

Europeanisation of Citizenship in the Successor States of the<br />

Former Yugoslavia (CITSEE) Working Paper Series No.<br />

2013/33 (2013): 23,<br />

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_i<br />

d=2388884.<br />

4 “EU Enlargement: Check Current Status,”<br />

European Commission, last modified April 16, <strong>2015</strong>,<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/enlargement/countries/checkcurrent-status/index_en.htm.<br />

3 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 3


erupted in Paris just as they did in<br />

Belgrade, Zagreb and Montenegro, which<br />

suggests that causality for anti-gay<br />

sentiment might not necessarily be rooted<br />

in EU conditionality but is likely a<br />

symptom of generalized homophobia. This<br />

paper presents the argument that the<br />

advancement of sexual minority rights<br />

comes at a cost regardless of whether it is<br />

endogenously or exogenously promulgated<br />

, and often with vitriol and protests<br />

targeted toward the very same minority<br />

groups expected to benefit from changes in<br />

the law. However, because the gains in<br />

legal status come with increased rights and<br />

remedies, it is a worthy and significant goal<br />

to pursue in spite of the costs.<br />

The paper concludes by posing<br />

relevant questions concerning the power of<br />

supranational organizations, and whether<br />

such organizations can facilitate the<br />

advancement of sexual minority rights.<br />

Taking the EU as a model, can other<br />

supranational organizations (World Trade<br />

Organization or the World Bank) impose<br />

membership requirements that ask not only<br />

for the respect of sexual minority rights via<br />

declaratory instruments but also impose<br />

strict enforcement, regulatory and<br />

disciplinary regimes for violating such<br />

rights?<br />

BACKGROUND<br />

Gender equality and nondiscrimination<br />

on the basis of sex, racial or<br />

ethnic origin, religion or belief, disability,<br />

age and sexual orientation are amongst the<br />

founding values of the European Union. 5<br />

Therefore, citizens of member states and,<br />

5 European Commission, “The EU Explained:<br />

Justice, Fundamental Rights and Equality,”<br />

Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union<br />

(2014): 4,<br />

http://europa.eu/pol/pdf/flipbook/en/justice_en.<br />

pdf.<br />

by extension, citizens of the supranational<br />

European Union are afforded equal rights<br />

regardless of gender or sexual orientation.<br />

A supranational organization lies<br />

somewhere between a confederation and a<br />

federation, but it does not fall exclusively<br />

into either category because there are<br />

several characteristics that are unique to<br />

this type of union. 6 For example, while<br />

competence is divided between the EU and<br />

the individual states, sovereignty remains<br />

exclusively within the realm of the member<br />

states. 7 Kiljunen 8 makes the point that EU<br />

legislation takes precedence over national<br />

laws in areas where the EU has been<br />

accorded competence, 9 just as U.S. federal<br />

law and the constitution take precedence<br />

over state law only in matters where the<br />

federal government has been granted such<br />

powers by the Constitution.<br />

The important concept here is that<br />

a supranational organization is a collective<br />

body of states acting through a central<br />

power in matters delegated to it by the<br />

individual states. The states defer to the<br />

supranational rule in the matters delegated<br />

to that union. The EU started as an<br />

economic union, but gradually expanded its<br />

scope. Social, political and human rights<br />

eventually made their way into the acquis<br />

communautaire. The acquis communautaire is<br />

defined as the “[c]ommon foundation of<br />

rights and obligations which binds together<br />

6 Kimmo Kiljunen, “The European Constitution in<br />

the Making,” Centre for European Policy Studies (2004):<br />

22,<br />

7 Ibid.<br />

8 “Composition: Representatives of the National<br />

Parliaments,” The European Convention, last visited<br />

April 16, 2014, http://europeanconvention.europa.eu/EN/Static/Static6cf8.html?la<br />

ng=EN&Content=Parlement_Nat. Kimmo<br />

Kiljunen is a former member of the Finnish<br />

Parliament and member of the European<br />

Convention that drafted a constitution for the EU.<br />

9 Kiljunen, “The European Constitution in the<br />

Making,” 19.<br />

4 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 4


the Member States of the European<br />

Union.” 10 It is derived from the French<br />

verb acquérir, which means to acquire, and<br />

therefore conjointly means that which the<br />

community has already acquired. This<br />

concept is important here because new<br />

members seeking to enter the union have<br />

to harmonize their national laws to grant<br />

those acquired European rights to their<br />

citizens as well. Hence, as the rights of<br />

sexual minorities became part of the<br />

European acquis in the 2000s, 11 the<br />

applicant countries from The Socialist<br />

Federal Republic of Yugoslavia (SFRY)<br />

had to enact non-discrimination legislation<br />

to protect sexual minorities.<br />

The SFRY was a federation of six<br />

socialist republics: Bosnia and<br />

Herzegovina, Croatia, Macedonia,<br />

Montenegro, Serbia, and Slovenia, which<br />

disintegrated in the 1990s as a result of a<br />

number of regional ethnic conflicts. These<br />

countries are pertinent because they<br />

constitute the majority of applicants<br />

currently negotiating for EU accession. 12<br />

While Croatia successfully acceded to the<br />

union in 2013, Serbia and Montenegro are<br />

still undergoing the negotiating phase. 13<br />

Moreover, these three countries are<br />

relevant to this study because despite their<br />

geographic proximity, they have distinctive<br />

narratives and imaginaries in EU accession.<br />

10 “Community Acqui,” EuroVoc: Multilingual<br />

Thesaurus of the European Union, last visited April 16,<br />

2014,<br />

http://eurovoc.europa.eu/drupal/?q=request&uri=<br />

http://eurovoc.europa.eu/210682.<br />

11 Council of the European Union, “Council<br />

Directive 2000/78/EC of 27 November 2000<br />

Establishing a General Framework for Equal<br />

Treatment in Employment and Occupation,” Official<br />

Journal of the European Communities (2000), http://eurlex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:32000L007<br />

8&rid=2.<br />

12 “EU Enlargement: Check Current Status,”<br />

European Commission.<br />

13 Ibid.<br />

This is especially seen vis-à-vis EU<br />

conditionality toward harmonization of<br />

sexual minority rights. 14<br />

LITERATURE REVIEW<br />

This analysis examines Kahlina’s<br />

paper in great depth because of her seminal<br />

work on the issue of sexual minority rights<br />

in the context of former Yugoslav<br />

republics’ accession to the EU. As a<br />

current and popular topic in human rights,<br />

there is however limited scholarship<br />

specifically on the issue of LGBT rights in<br />

the context of Western Balkan states. This<br />

paper not only builds on the work laid out<br />

by Kahlina but also offers a different<br />

perspective and analysis using secondary<br />

sources.<br />

Kahlina, in Contested Terrain of<br />

Sexual Citizenship: EU Accession and the<br />

Changing Position of Sexual Minorities in the<br />

Post-Yugoslav Context, explores the point<br />

brought forth by feminist and sexuality<br />

studies scholars that citizenship rights and<br />

duties are accorded differently on the basis<br />

of gender and sexuality. 15 The author<br />

submits that because citizenship is granted<br />

largely on the basis of ancestry, which is<br />

inevitably linked to reproductive and<br />

monogamous sexuality, society has an<br />

inherent bias toward heterosexuality. 16<br />

Throughout her paper, Kahlina discusses<br />

the tensions between nationalism, nationbuilding,<br />

and the transnational processes of<br />

EU accession and how these impacted<br />

sexual citizenship in the former Yugoslav<br />

republics. 17<br />

It is important to clarify Kahlina’s<br />

conceptions of “sexual citizenship” and<br />

“sexual minority.” Lister as quoted in<br />

14 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 11.<br />

15 Ibid., 1.<br />

16 Ibid., 1-2.<br />

17 Ibid., 1.<br />

5 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 5


Kahlina referred to sexual citizenship as<br />

“the ways in which sexuality is implicated<br />

in the scope of rights that form the basis of<br />

citizenship, such as civil, social, and cultural<br />

rights, and which determine the unequal<br />

citizenship status of sexual minorities, i.e.<br />

of those individuals whose sexual practices<br />

do not comply with the heterosexual<br />

norm.” 18 This paper will attempt to answer if<br />

the bundle of rights afforded to the sexual<br />

minority can be equalized to those of the<br />

majority in the EU. Kahlina presents the<br />

concept of “sexual minority” not in a<br />

quantitative sense but rather in terms of<br />

the power structure. 19 Alcoff and Mohanty<br />

as quoted in Kahlina posit the concept of<br />

minority within a “framework [that] signifies<br />

the non-hegemonic position that is formed<br />

on the grounds of its unequal relation to<br />

the dominant group.” 20 Following this<br />

definition, sexual minorities would consist<br />

of the group of people who have unequal<br />

power in comparison to the dominant<br />

group of heterosexuals in society.<br />

Kahlina submits that although<br />

sexual minority rights were already part of<br />

the EU legal discourse in the 2000s, they<br />

did not play a prominent role in the 2004<br />

and 2007 enlargements. 21 However, greater<br />

18 Ruth Lister, “Sexual Citizenship.” In Handbook of<br />

Citizenship Studies, eds. Engin F. Isin and Bryan S.<br />

Turner, 191-209. London: SAGE Publications Ltd.,<br />

2002. doi: 10.4135/9781848608276.n12, quoted in<br />

Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual Citizenship,”<br />

2.<br />

19 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 5.<br />

20 Linda Martín Alcoff and Satya P. Mohanty,<br />

“Reconsidering Identity Politics: An Introduction.”<br />

In Identity Politics Reconsidered, eds. Satya P. Mohanty,<br />

Linda Martín Alcoff, and Michael Hames-Garcia, 1-<br />

9. Gordonsville, VA, USA: Palgrave Macmillan,<br />

2006. Accessed May 1, <strong>2015</strong>. ProQuest ebrary,<br />

quoted in Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 5.<br />

21 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 9. The 2004 and 2007 enlargements<br />

emphasis was placed on sexual citizenship<br />

beginning with the accession of Croatia,<br />

Montenegro, and Serbia in the late 2000s. 22<br />

The author points to the European<br />

Commission Progress Report for Croatia and<br />

Article 33 of the EP Resolution 2012 on the<br />

European integration process of Serbia<br />

calling on the respective countries to do<br />

more against homophobia and to conform<br />

with European standards when it comes to<br />

protection of sexual minorities. 23 Kahlina<br />

purports that those stricter standards were<br />

imposed because of EU bias against the<br />

Western Balkan states, which were<br />

depicted as “backward,” “not civilized<br />

enough” and “not ‘European’ enough.” 24<br />

On the other hand, it could be<br />

argued that the EU’s motivation was<br />

sincerely founded upon a desire to create a<br />

more unified community that shared<br />

similar human rights values among other<br />

things. In Citizenship and the Problem of<br />

Community, Lynn A. Staeheli explains that<br />

citizenship is closely linked to community.<br />

She argues that “community is where<br />

contests are waged over membership and<br />

the political subjects and subjectivities that<br />

‘belong’ in a political community …<br />

[community] is a site in which power<br />

relationships are both expressed and<br />

solidified through citizenship formation.” 25<br />

Staehli suggests that citizenship is a<br />

struggle or contest to belong to a particular<br />

polity.<br />

included the following countries: Hungary, Poland,<br />

Romania, Slovakia, Latvia, Estonia, Lithuania,<br />

Bulgaria, Czech Republic and Slovenia. “EUROPA:<br />

The History of the European Union,” European<br />

Union, last visited April 16, 2014,<br />

http://europa.eu/about-eu/eu-history/2000-<br />

2009/index_en.htm.<br />

22 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 9.<br />

23 Ibid., 9-10.<br />

24 Ibid., 10.<br />

25 Lynn Staeheli, “Citizenship and the Problem of<br />

Community,” Political Geography 5, 7 (2008): 27.<br />

6 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 6


In studying how different<br />

communities in the Western Balkan states<br />

were imagined, Kahlina paid close<br />

attention to the sharp distinctions in the<br />

national imaginaries of the respective<br />

states. 26 Following the dissolution of the<br />

former Yugoslav federation, the previously<br />

repressed sense of ethnic belonging came<br />

to the forefront in the states once again. 27<br />

Kahlina finds that this concept of national<br />

imaginary built around ethnic identity is<br />

significant in the study of EU accession. In<br />

Croatia, for example, being more<br />

“European” was considered more desirable<br />

than being “Balkan,” which was the reverse<br />

in Serbia. 28 These distinctive discourses<br />

eventually led to different paths toward EU<br />

accession in the respective states. Building<br />

on national imaginaries can be a powerful<br />

tool for social change. Western<br />

democracies often pride themselves on<br />

issues such as inclusion of minorities,<br />

tolerance, and human rights. It is a way to<br />

mark their difference from the others. 29<br />

National imaginaries translate into<br />

legal realities. Kahlina explains that<br />

conceptions of nation, gender and sexuality<br />

define the citizenship status of sexual<br />

minorities because they not only relate in a<br />

cultural context but also in the allocation of<br />

rights through family codes, citizenship and<br />

immigration acts, and labor and health<br />

26 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 11-12.<br />

27 Thomas Hylland Eriksen, Social Identity, Intergroup<br />

Conflict, and Conflict Reduction, eds. Richard D.<br />

Ashmore, Lee Jussim & David Wilder (2001), 47-<br />

51.<br />

28 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 11.<br />

29 Fred Joseph LeBlanc, “Sporting<br />

Homonationalism: Russian Homophobia,<br />

Imaginative Geographies & the 2014 Sochi<br />

Olympic Games” (presentation, Sociology<br />

Association of Aotearoa New Zealand, Annual<br />

Conference December 2013)<br />

https://otago.academia.edu/FredLeBlanc/Confere<br />

nce-Presentations.<br />

insurance laws. 30 Kahlina, however, stops<br />

short from endorsing the concept of<br />

Europeanization of the Western Balkan<br />

states as a definite and progressive change<br />

in the national imaginaries that results in<br />

greater inclusion of sexual minorities. She<br />

suggests that importing Western European<br />

standards has also provided ammunition to<br />

conservative and nationalist groups to<br />

disenfranchise and discriminate against<br />

sexual minority groups, implying that there<br />

was no clear advancement of sexual<br />

minority rights as a result of the Western<br />

Balkan states’ legislative harmonization<br />

with EU requirements. Kahlina therefore<br />

suggests that the EU was not necessarily an<br />

unambiguous liberator of the oppressed<br />

sexual minorities in the former Yugoslav<br />

republics. She specifically cautions against<br />

the assumption that a Europeanization<br />

movement would become a protector of<br />

local LGBT populations. 31<br />

In fact, changes in the legal code<br />

that decriminalized homosexuality did not<br />

occur at the same time across the former<br />

Yugoslav states, Kahlina argues. It was not<br />

a single Europeanization wave that swept<br />

decriminalization of homosexuality<br />

through Yugoslavia at a particular point in<br />

time. Decriminalization of homosexuality<br />

actually began in 1977, long before EU<br />

accession, at a time when criminal law<br />

shifted from federal to the state level—<br />

Slovenia, Croatia, and Montenegro, and the<br />

Province of Vojvodina decriminalized in<br />

1977 but Serbia waited until 1994. 32 Serbia<br />

was actually one of the last countries in the<br />

Eastern European block to address the<br />

issue of homosexuality altogether. In fact,<br />

it took 15 years after the 1994<br />

30 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 4.<br />

31 Ibid., 5.<br />

32 Douglas Sanders, “Getting Lesbian and Gay<br />

Issues on the International Human Rights Agenda,”<br />

Human Rights Quarterly 67, 71 (1996): 18.<br />

7 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 7


decriminalization for the country to enact<br />

the first law banning discrimination based<br />

on sexual orientation, and it would not be<br />

until 2009 that the first non-violent gay<br />

pride parade took place. 33 The relative<br />

speed of change in Serbia is arguably<br />

slower compared to the neighboring<br />

countries, and the possible reasons behind<br />

this particular Serbian exception will be<br />

examined below.<br />

As SFRY broke up in 1992,<br />

Ragazzi and Sťiks explain, the successor<br />

states used their “founding documents,<br />

constitutions and citizenship laws as<br />

effective tools to accelerate nation-building<br />

and to ‘ethnically engineer’ their<br />

populations to the advantage of the<br />

majority ethnic group.” 34 The authors<br />

argued that the new citizenship laws both<br />

“deterritorialised inclusion and targeted<br />

exclusion” because in Croatia, for example,<br />

Croatian ethnicity at its core was used “not<br />

only to homogenise the national<br />

population through the exclusion of non-<br />

Croats, but also to include all ethnic Croats<br />

in a single national group, regardless of<br />

their place or country of residence.” 35<br />

In Negotiating Interests: Women and<br />

Nationalism in Serbia and Croatia, 1990-1997,<br />

Lilly and Irvine submit that nationalist<br />

ideologies in Serbia and Croatia reflect the<br />

concept of nation as a patriarchal family,<br />

assigning the role of the father in the<br />

public sphere as soldiers and workers, and<br />

positioning women to the private sphere as<br />

“reproducers and socializers of future<br />

citizens” teaching them the nation’s<br />

33 Bojana Dunjić-Kostić et al., “Knowledge: A<br />

Possible Tool in Shaping Medical Professionals’<br />

Attitudes Towards Homosexuality,” Psychiatria<br />

Danubina 24, 2 (2012): 143-144.<br />

34 Francesco Ragazzi & Igor Štiks, Citizenship Policies<br />

in the New Europe, eds. Rainer Bauböck, Bernhard<br />

Perchinig & Wiebke Sievers (2009), 339.<br />

35 Ibid.<br />

“history, traditions, culture, and values.” 36<br />

As such, women are framed as not only<br />

carriers of the genetic material of the ethnic<br />

group but also as transmitters of the<br />

cultural ethnicity. Heterosexuality emerged<br />

as the dominant and only legitimate form<br />

of sexual relationship, which de facto<br />

delegitimized other sexualities for the sake<br />

of the nation—this of course paved the<br />

way for exclusionary laws that made<br />

citizenship particularly difficult for sexual, 37<br />

and arguably, other minority groups.<br />

After the first decade of the<br />

breakup of the SFRY, Jović explains that a<br />

new consensus emerged towards<br />

Europeanization—notions of nationalism<br />

in Croatia were not necessarily being<br />

rejected but on the contrary, they were<br />

being secured by ensuring continuity of the<br />

nation through membership in powerful<br />

institutions such as the NATO and the<br />

EU. 38 It was a means to ensure Croatia’s<br />

survival as an independent state would not<br />

be challenged. 39 Kahlina posits that the<br />

defining or redefining of what it is to be<br />

Croatian or Serbian probably started<br />

around the same time as a result of the<br />

socio-political and symbolic processes of<br />

EU accession. 40 The question of what it is<br />

to be European was therefore posed, and,<br />

as a result, the place for sexual and other<br />

minorities also became part of the<br />

discourse. Ultimately, the question<br />

becomes whether these new aspiring EU<br />

states would become more like the<br />

36 Carol S. Lilly & Jill A. Irvine, “Negotiating<br />

Interests: Women and Nationalism in Serbia and<br />

Croatia, 1990-1997,” Eastern European Politics and<br />

Societies, 16 (2002): 112.<br />

37 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 7-8.<br />

38 Dejan Jović, The Western Balkans and the EU: ‘The<br />

Hour of Europe’, ed. Jacques Rupnik (Institute for<br />

Security Studies European Union, 2011), 40-41.<br />

39 Ibid.<br />

40 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 9.<br />

8 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 8


Western European nations, where<br />

difference and inclusiveness is a matter of<br />

national pride, or if they would follow a<br />

different trajectory.<br />

Croatia applied for EU<br />

membership in 2003, followed by<br />

Montenegro in 2008 and Serbia in 2009,<br />

and last year, in 2013, Croatia’s application<br />

was approved making it the 28 th member of<br />

the Union. 41 Montenegro and Serbia are<br />

still in the negotiation phase. 42 Kahlina<br />

posits that although desire to join the EU<br />

was “largely present” in the former<br />

Yugoslav republics, legal improvements for<br />

sexual minorities were however “portrayed<br />

as part of European values and EU<br />

conditionality . . . [which] in turn<br />

influenced the joining of homophobic,<br />

nationalist, religious, and anti-EU<br />

discourses in the mobilization against the<br />

transformation of sexual citizenship.” 43<br />

Sexual minority rights did not come<br />

as a pre-condition for accession until the<br />

2000s. 44 Kochenov points out that<br />

discrimination against sexual minorities was<br />

not raised as an issue until Council Directive<br />

2000/78/EC, which stated that<br />

“[d]iscrimination based on . . . sexual<br />

orientation may undermine the<br />

achievement of the objectives of the EC<br />

Treaty,” 45 and Kahlina points out that the<br />

issue similarly was not raised until the year<br />

2000 in the Charter of Fundamental Rights of<br />

41 “EU Enlargement: Check Current Status,”<br />

European Commission.<br />

42 Ibid.<br />

43 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 9.<br />

44 Ibid.<br />

45 Dimitry Kochenov, “Democracy and Human<br />

Rights - Not for Gay People?: EU Eastern<br />

Enlargement and its Impact on the Protection of<br />

the Rights of Sexual Minorities,” Texan Wesleyan<br />

Law Review 13, 2 (2007): 487,<br />

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_i<br />

d=1022307.<br />

the European Union. 46 It is noteworthy that in<br />

2000 the following member states, part of<br />

the original 15, still did not have antidiscrimination<br />

laws protecting the<br />

employment rights of sexual minorities :<br />

United Kingdom, Germany, Italy, Belgium,<br />

Greece, Portugal and Austria. 47 They<br />

passed such legislations in 2003. 48<br />

But after Council Directive<br />

2000/78/EC and the Charter of Fundamental<br />

Rights of the European Union in 2000 and the<br />

subsequent legislative harmonization in the<br />

above EU member states, nondiscrimination<br />

on the basis of sexual<br />

orientation became a more pronounced<br />

European value. Therefore, countries that<br />

wanted to become more European or that<br />

had aspirations to join the EU, Kahlina<br />

suggests, probably started viewing<br />

movements toward liberal pluralism more<br />

favorably. 49 This can be argued in the case<br />

of Croatia where, following the dissolution<br />

of SFRY, strong anti-Balkanist sentiment<br />

46 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 9. The charter specifies “[a]ny<br />

discrimination based on any ground such as sex,<br />

race, colour, ethnic or social origin, genetic features,<br />

language, religion or belief, political or any other<br />

opinion, membership of a national minority,<br />

property, birth, disability, age or sexual orientation<br />

shall be prohibited.” European Convention,<br />

“Charter of Fundamental Rights of the European<br />

Union,” Official Journal of the European Communities<br />

(2000) (emphasis added),<br />

http://www.europarl.europa.eu/charter/pdf/text_e<br />

n.pdf.<br />

47 Robert Wintemute, “Sexual Orientation and<br />

Gender Identity Discrimination: The Case Law of<br />

the European Court of Human Rights and the<br />

Court of Justice of the European Union,” ILGA-<br />

Europe (2013): 1, http://www.ilgaeurope.org/content/download/19297/124445/vers<br />

ion/4/file/Council+of+Europe+(Comm+for+HR<br />

)+2013-10-21.pdf. Notable exceptions in the list of<br />

the original 15, which passed such antidiscrimination<br />

provisions prior 2000 include France<br />

in 1985, and Denmark and Sweden in 1987. Ibid.<br />

48 Ibid.<br />

49 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 11.<br />

9 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 9


fueled the country, and because Croatians<br />

saw themselves more as Europeans they<br />

perceived EU accession as their grand<br />

return to Europe. They therefore became<br />

more accommodating to the imported<br />

European non-discrimination values—a<br />

cause which united both right and left wing<br />

politicians of the country. 50 Therefore from<br />

a Croatian perspective, it made sense to<br />

return to Europe given their selfperception,<br />

and they also understood it was<br />

in their security interest to become part of<br />

the EU and NATO.<br />

Kahlina argues that the same was<br />

not necessarily true for Serbia, however,<br />

and that Montenegro found itself<br />

somewhere in the middle of these two<br />

extremes. 51 Montenegrins did not view the<br />

Europe and Balkan notions as mutually<br />

opposing, and like Croatia, Montenegrin<br />

politicians, both left and right, were united<br />

behind the cause of EU accession. 52 These<br />

different perceptions of local attitudes<br />

toward Europe and the Balkans ultimately<br />

had an impact on the feasibility of the<br />

adoption of the imported European values.<br />

Whether the adoption of these<br />

imported European values is genuine and<br />

effective is another story, but what remains<br />

true and enduring is that mechanisms,<br />

structures, policies, and institutions<br />

required in the acceding countries can and<br />

will ultimately have an important impact in<br />

the facilitation and genuine integration of<br />

such values in civil society. Antidiscrimination<br />

laws and institutions that<br />

should monitor their implementation are<br />

now an inevitable part of the obligations<br />

imposed in the EU accession process. 53<br />

The EU, through its delegations and<br />

monitoring instruments in the acceding<br />

countries, can serve as an important<br />

50 Ibid.<br />

51 Ibid., 11-12.<br />

52 Ibid., 12.<br />

53 Ibid.<br />

promoter for the advancement of sexual<br />

minority rights in the respective states.<br />

These delegations paid particularly close<br />

attention to the Gay Pride Marches<br />

because they were seen as an important<br />

and visible “marker of democratization and<br />

human rights promotion,” argues<br />

Kahlina. 54<br />

In State-Sponsored Homophobia and the<br />

Denial of the Right of Assembly in Central and<br />

Eastern Europe: The “Boomerang” and the<br />

“Ricochet” between European Organizations and<br />

Civil Society to Uphold Human Rights,<br />

Holzhacker argues that gay pride marches<br />

are more than just symbolic public displays.<br />

These marches “communicate specific<br />

political and societal demands to elites,<br />

including social acceptance, the need for<br />

equality and antidiscrimination laws, as well<br />

as the recognition of same-sex partnerships<br />

and marriage.” 55 Holzhacker goes so far as<br />

to say that not providing adequate<br />

protection to participants or banning the<br />

gay pride marches altogether is a form of<br />

state-sponsored homophobia. The author<br />

argues that “such state action serves to<br />

legitimize homophobia in the broader<br />

society; cues other actors, such as<br />

employers, to engage in discriminatory<br />

behavior, and emboldens those who use<br />

verbal and violent attacks in the streets<br />

against [LGBT] persons who wish to<br />

exercise their right of assembly to bring<br />

about social and legal change.” 56<br />

Although gay pride marches may<br />

attract greater opposition, they are one of<br />

the few visual indicators available to the<br />

EU delegations and human rights watchers.<br />

54 Ibid., 15-16.<br />

55 Ronald Holzhacker, “State-Sponsored<br />

Homophobia and the Denial of the Right of<br />

Assembly in Central and Eastern Europe: The<br />

“Boomerang” and the “Ricochet” between<br />

European Organizations and Civil Society to<br />

Uphold Human Rights,” Law & Policy 1, 3 (2012):<br />

35.<br />

56 Ibid., 2.<br />

10 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 10


Also, these marches are not just symbolic<br />

because they are also the very embodiment<br />

of the human right of assembly, codified in<br />

articles 10 and 11 of the Declaration of<br />

Rights of Man and Citizen (1789), the First<br />

Amendment to the U.S. Constitution, and<br />

in various regional European human rights<br />

treaties, notably article 11 of the European<br />

Convention on Human Rights (ECHR)<br />

and article 12 of the Charter of<br />

Fundamental Rights of the European<br />

Union. 57 Gay Pride embodies the political<br />

right of assembly. If the right of assembly<br />

cannot be protected, it is improbable that<br />

other rights such as protection from<br />

discrimination or even marriage equality<br />

could ever be achieved. For this reason, it<br />

is an important symbol that can be used by<br />

delegations to measure the extent of<br />

protection afforded to sexual minorities.<br />

The first Pride March in Belgrade<br />

took place in 2001, but was cut short<br />

because of the eruption of violent<br />

protests. 58 Instead of arranging for greater<br />

police protection, the second Pride March<br />

organized eight years later in 2009 was<br />

cancelled by city authorities out of fear that<br />

the march would erupt into widespread<br />

violence. 59 A year later, in 2010, the<br />

Belgrade Pride under the watchful eye of<br />

the head of the EU mission in Serbia,<br />

Vincent Degert, who said it was a moment<br />

to “celebrate the values of tolerance,<br />

freedom of expression and assembly," was<br />

again met with violent protests culminating<br />

in more than 100 people being injured,<br />

mostly police, and around another 100<br />

people being arrested. 60 The Pride March<br />

57 Ibid., 3.<br />

58 Mark Lowen, “Gay March Plan Tests Serb<br />

Feelings,” BBC News, last modified September 19,<br />

2009,<br />

http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/europe/8263116.stm.<br />

59 Ibid.<br />

60 Mark Lowen, “Scores Arrested in Belgrade after<br />

Anti-gay Riot,” BBC News, last modified October<br />

was again cancelled in 2011, 2012, and<br />

2013 by the government citing fears of<br />

violent protests, which raised concerns at<br />

the European Commission when<br />

considering Serbian membership to the<br />

EU. 61<br />

Serbian resistance to inclusion of<br />

sexual minorities have come under various<br />

pretexts. Kahlina brings forth the issue of<br />

White Plague in Serbia, which is a term used<br />

to describe the decreasing birthrates and<br />

resulting insufficient reproduction of<br />

ethnically pure Serb-citizens. 62 The White<br />

Plague is closely linked to the concept of<br />

lineage and became a dominant theme<br />

following the breakup of SFRY in the<br />

1990s. 63 Per this framework, “nonreproductive<br />

practices and nonheterosexual<br />

identities were perceived as a<br />

direct threat to the nation . . . [and were to]<br />

be excluded from belonging to the national<br />

community.” 64 Kahlina points out how<br />

some activists organized anti-Pride protests<br />

called Family Pride under the White Plague<br />

theme, which framed the future existence<br />

of the pure Serbian nation as being<br />

compromised by an aggressive movement<br />

of the LGBT community. 65<br />

Pride Marches in the other<br />

acceding countries did not go without<br />

disruption either, but they were less violent<br />

than Belgrade’s. Zagreb held its first Pride<br />

10, 2010, http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/worldeurope-11507253.<br />

61 Julia Druelle, “La Serbie Interdit la Gay Pride<br />

pour la Troisième Année Consécutive” [Serbia Bans<br />

Gay Pride for the Third Consecutive Year], Le<br />

Monde, last modified September 28, 2013,<br />

http://www.lemonde.fr/europe/article/2013/09/2<br />

8/la-serbie-interdit-la-gay-pride-pour-la-troisiemeannee-consecutive_3486625_3214.html.<br />

62 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 21.<br />

63 Ibid.<br />

64 Ibid.<br />

65 Ibid.<br />

11 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 11


in 2002, 66 and Montenegro did not have its<br />

first march until 2013. 67 Right of assembly<br />

is a core European value and human right,<br />

and Serbia’s consecutive cancellations of<br />

the Gay Pride marches have raised serious<br />

concerns at the EU. The Swedish Minister<br />

for European Affairs, Birgitta Ohlsson,<br />

stated in 2012 that the recent Gay Pride<br />

bans has damaged Serbia’s membership<br />

bid, and she also stressed that membership<br />

in the union comes with “commitment to<br />

human rights, commitment to minority<br />

rights, commitment to freedom of speech,<br />

commitment to freedom of assembly.<br />

These are the core values of the union.<br />

LGBT-rights are human rights.” 68<br />

Similarly, commenting on the<br />

violence at the first Split Pride in Croatia in<br />

2011, the Dutch EU MP Marije<br />

Cornelissen, who participated in the<br />

parade, explained that the violence in Split<br />

showed that “Croatia still ha[d] a lot to do<br />

to properly protect human rights” and to<br />

firmly combat homophobia. 69 Stella<br />

Ronner Grubačić, Ambassador of the<br />

Kingdom of the Netherlands in Croatia,<br />

went even further and stated that the EU<br />

should more closely monitor Croatia in<br />

66 “Croatian Gays Join First 'Pride' March,” BBC<br />

News, last modified June 29, 2002,<br />

http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/europe/2074653.stm.<br />

67 “Monténégro: Incidents en Marge de la Première<br />

Gay Pride” [Montenegro: Incidents at the First Gay<br />

Pride], Le Parisien, last modified October 20, 2013,<br />

http://www.leparisien.fr/flash-actualitemonde/montenegro-incidents-en-marge-de-lapremiere-gay-pride-20-10-2013-3243477.php.<br />

68 “Cancelled Pride Festival Damages Serbia’s EU<br />

Membership Bid,” Alliance of Liberals and Democrats<br />

for Europe Party, last modified October 8, 2012,<br />

http://www.aldeparty.eu/en/news/cancelled-pridefestival-damages-serbias-eu-membership-bid.<br />

69 “Unsafe Pride Event in Croatia Casts Shadow<br />

over Accession Prospects,” The European Parliament's<br />

Intergroup on LGBT Rights, last modified June 13,<br />

2011, http://www.lgbt-ep.eu/press-releases/unsafepride-event-in-croatia-casts-shadow-over-accessionprospects.<br />

relation to the accession process following<br />

the violent protests at the 2011 march. 70 It<br />

is likely that these marches were serving as<br />

important social indicators to EU officials<br />

in evaluating whether the acceding<br />

countries were indeed endorsing and<br />

practicing European values of inclusion<br />

and respect for minority rights.<br />

ANALYSIS<br />

Kahlina’s paper maintains a<br />

conservative approach in giving the EU<br />

accession process credit for advancing<br />

sexual citizenship in the former Yugoslav<br />

republics. In contrast, this paper will<br />

examine the significance of EU-inspired<br />

legislative reform. Regardless of whether<br />

endogenously or exogenously promulgated,<br />

such reforms are arguably always<br />

accompanied with local strife, and in the<br />

end, either path, local or supranational, can<br />

ultimately lead to significant advances in<br />

sexual minority rights. The important point<br />

to analyze here is : (1) whether setting the<br />

law in a hierarchical manner in a<br />

supranational context can be effective in<br />

transforming sexual citizenship and<br />

assuring equal rights, or (2) whether the<br />

advancement of sexual minorities come<br />

from the groundswell support of the<br />

individual peoples constituting a nation.<br />

Kahlina suggests a cautious<br />

approach in examining the effectiveness of<br />

a supranational approach in advancing<br />

sexual minority rights, but it can be argued<br />

that both approaches, supranational and<br />

local, acting individually or in concert with<br />

each other, can lead to significant gains in<br />

the cause of sexual citizenship. However,<br />

70 “Gay Pride u Zagrebu: Nova Kušnja Tolerancije<br />

u Hrvatskoj” [Gay Pride in Zagreb: New Test of<br />

Tolerance in Croatia], Deutsche Welle, last modified<br />

June 18, 2011, http://www.dw.de/gay-pride-u-<br />

zagrebu-nova-kušnja-tolerancije-u-hrvatskoj/a-<br />

15170887.<br />

12 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 12


to become most transformative, these<br />

battles should probably be fought both at<br />

the supranational law level and at the local<br />

level by civil society organizations. Often<br />

times, it is via the engagement of the local<br />

NGOs using supranational law to pressure<br />

their governments that advancement in<br />

sexual citizenship can be most effectively<br />

attained. 71 However, this analysis finds that,<br />

even alone, EU-inspired legislative reform<br />

can become an effective instrument to<br />

ensure equal citizenship rights.<br />

It is also quite possible that the EU<br />

process is not the actual cause of the<br />

mobilization of religious and nationalist<br />

groups against local gay communities, but<br />

the very nature of the legal reforms<br />

themselves. Whether via the<br />

instrumentation of the EU or that of any<br />

other institution at the local, national,<br />

regional, supranational or even<br />

international level, the advancement for<br />

equal rights has almost always been<br />

accompanied by violent protests of the<br />

powerful ruling majorities, regardless of the<br />

impetus for reform.<br />

Considering France, a progressive<br />

country in Western Europe and founding<br />

member of the EU, for example, it<br />

legalized same sex marriage just in May<br />

2013 – this legislative act came into<br />

existence only after months of severe and<br />

violent protests by the hundreds of<br />

thousands in the streets of Paris. 72 The<br />

71 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 13-14. Montenegro, for example, has<br />

been slow in implementing legal protections for the<br />

LGBT community, and one of the reasons could be<br />

although in the midst of pre-existing supranational<br />

law, there was low pressure from local activists,<br />

who became more organized and visible only<br />

recently.<br />

72 Steven Erlanger, “Hollande Signs French Gay<br />

Marriage Law,” New York Times, last modified May<br />

8, 2013,<br />

http://www.nytimes.com/2013/05/19/world/euro<br />

pe/hollande-signs-french-gay-marriagemain<br />

right wing party of former President<br />

Nicolas Sarkozy, the Union pour un<br />

Mouvement Populaire [Union for a<br />

Popular Movement] was opposed to the<br />

same-sex marriage law. 73 The radical right<br />

wing parties, the Front National 74 and the<br />

Parti Chrétien-Démocrate [Christian<br />

Democrat] were also against it. 75 In<br />

addition, almost all religious groups in<br />

France united against the proposed law. 76<br />

On November 17, 2012, there were 70,000<br />

activists, according to police, and 200,000,<br />

as reported by protest organizers, in Paris<br />

rallying against same sex marriage – the<br />

same month that the draft bill was<br />

submitted in Parliament. 77 On January 13,<br />

2013, there were 340,000, according to the<br />

police, and 1 million, per organizers,<br />

law.html?_r=1&.<br />

73 Laura Smith-Spark, “French Lawmakers Approve<br />

Same-Sex Marriage Bill,” CNN.com, last modified<br />

April 24, 2013,<br />

http://edition.cnn.com/2013/04/23/world/europe<br />

/france-same-sex-vote.<br />

74 “Contre le “Mariage Pour Tous”, Marine Le Pen<br />

en Appelle au Principe de Précaution” [Marine Le<br />

Pen Against Marriage for Everyone], 20 Minutes, last<br />

modified January 27, 2013,<br />

http://www.20minutes.fr/ledirect/1088305/contre<br />

-mariage-tous-marine-pen-appelle-principeprecaution.<br />

75 Alexandre Lemarié, “Christine Boutin: “Il y a des<br />

Lois Supérieures à la Loi de la République””<br />

[Christine Boutin: There are Superior Laws than the<br />

Laws of the Republic], Le Monde, last modified May<br />

20, 2013,<br />

http://www.lemonde.fr/politique/article/2013/05<br />

/20/christine-boutin-il-y-a-des-lois-superieures-a-laloi-de-la-republique_3378882_823448.html.<br />

76 Bernadette Sauvaget, “Les Cathos sur la Voie du<br />

Veto” [Catholics on the Path to Veto], Libération,<br />

last modified May 10, 2012,<br />

http://www.liberation.fr/societe/2012/05/10/lescathos-sur-la-voie-du-veto_817881.<br />

77 “Mariage Gay: Entre 70,000 et 200,000<br />

Opposants ont défilé à Paris” [Gay Marriage:<br />

Between 70,000 to 200,000 Opponents Marched in<br />

Paris], Le Parisien, last modified November 17, 2012,<br />

http://www.leparisien.fr/societe/mariage-gay-les-<br />

opposants-se-rassemblent-a-paris-et-en-province-<br />

17-11-2012-2329543.php.<br />

13 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 13


assembled in Paris against same sex<br />

marriage. 78<br />

In addition to protests on the<br />

streets, homophobic violence also tripled<br />

during the time the law was under<br />

consideration. 79 In 2013, in less than a sixmonth<br />

period, the number of homophobic<br />

violence reported to the nonprofit SOS<br />

Homophobie had already equaled the 2012<br />

record, which was in itself already 27<br />

percent higher than the previous year. 80 In<br />

April 2013, a month before the enactment<br />

of same-sex marriage in France, SOS<br />

Homophobie confirmed in a communiqué<br />

that it was a receiving about 10 reports of<br />

homophobic violence a day, which was<br />

three times the level of the year before. 81 A<br />

different organization, Refuge, which hosts<br />

young gays and lesbians between 15 and 25<br />

years old rejected by their families, also saw<br />

a tripling in the number of phone calls they<br />

were receiving. 82 Refuge confirmed that<br />

since December of 2012 when the debate<br />

on same-sex marriage had just started in<br />

Parliament, the number of phone calls<br />

reached around 400 to 450 a month in<br />

78 “Opposition au Mariage Gay: Le Récit de la<br />

Journée de Manifestation” [Opposition to Gay<br />

Marriage: A Day of Protest], Le Parisien, last<br />

modified January 13, 2013,<br />

http://www.leparisien.fr/societe/en-direct-lesopposants-au-mariage-gay-defilent-deja-en-outremer-13-01-2013-2476941.php.<br />

79 “Homophobie: Un Nouveau “Record””<br />

[Homophobia: A New “Record”], Marianne, last<br />

modified September 4, 2013,<br />

http://www.marianne.net/Homophobie-unnouveau-record_a231754.html.<br />

80 Ibid.<br />

81 Michaël Szadkowski & François Béguin, “Des<br />

Associations Dénoncent la "Radicalisation" des<br />

Actes Homophobes” [LGBT Organizations<br />

Denounce Rise in Radical Homophobic Acts], Le<br />

Monde, last modified April 9, 2013,<br />

http://www.lemonde.fr/societe/article/2013/04/0<br />

8/des-associations-denoncent-une-radicalisationdes-actes-homophobes_3156119_3224.html#.<br />

82 Ibid.<br />

comparison to just around 150 calls a<br />

month before the debate. 83<br />

Nicolas Noguier, president and<br />

founder of Refuge, explained that he does<br />

not think that there is as a radical increase<br />

in homophobic violence in France as much<br />

as there is a revelation of the existing hidden<br />

homophobia. 84 Noguier argued that the<br />

marriage debate in fact only highlighted or<br />

provoked a public expression of existing<br />

homophobia. He emphasized that the<br />

debate around marriage equality had<br />

ultimately allowed for the “liberation of<br />

this homophobic expression” which had to<br />

be put out in the open anyway. 85 For<br />

Noguier, the new marriage equality law was<br />

“necessary,” but it was accompanied by<br />

“important collateral damage” as well. 86<br />

The sociocultural and geopolitical<br />

dynamics in France and the former<br />

Yugoslav republics are worlds apart, and<br />

yet in both cases advances in sexual<br />

minority rights have yielded similar<br />

aggressive protests and opposition. If equal<br />

citizenship rights were truly a Western<br />

European concept, how are such rights<br />

also vehemently opposed when it came<br />

down to the legalization of same-sex<br />

marriage in France in 2013? Could it be<br />

that public debates on equal citizenship<br />

and the visibility of gay pride marches are<br />

not the cause but the revelation of existing<br />

homophobia, as explained above by<br />

Noguier? In colloquial language, are public<br />

debates around same-sex marriage in<br />

France or Gay Prides in the former<br />

Yugoslav republics bringing homophobia<br />

out of the closet but not necessarily causing<br />

it?<br />

Regardless of whether these<br />

debates are the cause or the revelation of<br />

homophobia, stating the law of the land or<br />

83 Ibid.<br />

84 Ibid.<br />

85 Ibid.<br />

86 Ibid.<br />

14 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 14


egion in favor of equal rights can<br />

ultimately lead to significant gains for<br />

minority communities, even if such legal<br />

changes also spur violent opposition. The<br />

net effect seems positive in the end. Taking<br />

the United States for example, after the<br />

landmark U.S. Supreme Court case, Brown<br />

v. Board of Education, which held that racially<br />

segregated educational facilities were<br />

inherently unequal, in spite of the massive<br />

and violent resistance organized across the<br />

Southern states, the ultimate impact of<br />

Brown was groundbreaking for the civil<br />

rights movement and for the integration of<br />

African Americans in civil society. In June<br />

2013, the Supreme Court in United States v.<br />

Windsor held that the federal government<br />

could not discriminate against same-sex<br />

couples and that the Defense of Marriage<br />

Act was unconstitutional. 87 The Windsor<br />

decision led to a number of cases in lower<br />

courts around the country on the issue of<br />

same-sex marriage prohibitions. The<br />

important point to note here is the<br />

implications of an overarching law, which<br />

states or smaller jurisdictions have to<br />

subsequently follow. Whether it is U.S.<br />

federal law determined by the Supreme<br />

Court or EU supranational law, stating<br />

87 Alison M. Smith, “Same-Sex Marriage: A Legal<br />

Background after United States v. Windsor,”<br />

Congressional Research Service, (2014): 1,<br />

https://fas.org/sgp/crs/misc/R43481.pdf. As of<br />

October 2014, there were already 18 states:<br />

California, Connecticut, Colorado, Delaware,<br />

Hawaii, Illinois, Iowa, Maine, Maryland,<br />

Massachusetts, Minnesota, New Hampshire, New<br />

Jersey, New Mexico, New York, Rhode Island,<br />

Vermont, Washington, and the District of<br />

Columbia that allow for same-sex marriage.<br />

Following Windsor, federal district courts in Utah,<br />

Oklahoma, Virginia, Michigan, and Texas have<br />

struck down same sex marriage bans in those states.<br />

Id. at 5. In Kentucky and Ohio, federal district<br />

courts held that they are to recognize same-sex<br />

marriages validly entered in other jurisdictions. Id. at<br />

7. All these rulings have been stayed pending<br />

appeal. Id.<br />

equal status of minorities in the eyes of the<br />

law goes a long way not only in advancing<br />

their legal status but also leads to a greater<br />

fulfillment of the promise of citizenship.<br />

This is illustrated by the gradual integration<br />

of African Americans in “white-only”<br />

public schools or the grant of marriage<br />

rights to gays and lesbians, at least at the<br />

Federal level for the time being.<br />

EU accession is an attractive<br />

economic and national security goal, and<br />

tying membership conditions with equal<br />

rights and non-discrimination against<br />

sexual minorities ultimately promises more<br />

good than harm. Opposition against full<br />

citizenship rights for sexual minorities<br />

happens in other places where EU<br />

accession is not a factor at all, from<br />

Uganda to progressive France. Reforming<br />

the law and establishing institutions to<br />

monitor implementation of these laws as a<br />

condition of membership can be an<br />

effective instrument to ensure full<br />

citizenship rights for sexual minorities.<br />

Today, all three states: Croatia, Serbia and<br />

Montenegro have anti-discrimination acts<br />

that explicitly condemn discrimination<br />

against sexual minorities, and they have<br />

also set up instruments to report and<br />

monitor any such discrimination. 88<br />

88 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 12-14. The following offices have<br />

been set up: in Croatia, there is an Ombudsperson<br />

for Gender Equality; in Serbia, a Commissioner for<br />

the Protection of Equality, and there is an office for<br />

the Protector of Human Rights and Freedoms of<br />

Montenegro. Other legal changes also took effect in<br />

the former Yugoslav republics – a Same-Sex<br />

Partnership Act was passed in Croatia although it<br />

provided only a few limited rights to same-sex<br />

couples instead full marriage rights. Before the<br />

Zakon o suzbijanju diskriminacije [Anti- discrimination<br />

Act] in 2008, which explicitly banned discrimination<br />

on the basis of sexual orientation, gender identity<br />

and gender expression, the Croatian Parliament had<br />

already incorporated anti-discrimination stipulations<br />

in a number of acts covering social, economic and<br />

political life, namely: the Zakon o radu [Labor Act],<br />

15 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 15


These legal changes were often<br />

presented by local politicians as<br />

exogenously imposed requirements on<br />

states applying for membership to the<br />

EU. 89 However, regardless of the EUscapegoating,<br />

the fact remains that these<br />

countries are passing laws to protect sexual<br />

minorities on a number of civic, social and<br />

political fronts. Positioning the move<br />

toward equal citizenship for gays and<br />

lesbians as EU-imposed does not take away<br />

from the very fact that in the end: equality<br />

in the eyes of the law for such minorities is<br />

achieved. Becoming equal in the eyes of<br />

the law is no small feat. If the law of the<br />

land of an EU member country is to hold<br />

any meaning—it follows that justice and<br />

remedies should become eventually<br />

accessible and achievable.<br />

The Ombudsperson for Gender<br />

Equality in Croatia indeed plays an<br />

important role in monitoring the<br />

implementation of the Anti-discrimination<br />

Act. The office is responsible for the<br />

investigation of individual complaints and<br />

to provide assistance to petitioners about<br />

discrimination based on sex, marital or<br />

the Zakon o medijima [Media Law], the Zakon o sportu<br />

[Sport Act], and the Zakon o znanosti i visokom<br />

obrazovanju [Science and Higher Education Act]<br />

among others. Similarly in Serbia, before passing<br />

the Zakon o zabrani diskriminacije [Anti-discrimination<br />

Act] in 2009, explicitly forbidding discrimination on<br />

the basis of gender identity and sexual orientation,<br />

the country also enacted stipulations banning<br />

discrimination against sexual minorities in a number<br />

of laws, namely: the Zakon o javnom informisanju<br />

[Public Informing Act], the Zakon o radu [Labor<br />

Act], the Zakon o visokom obrazovanju [Higher<br />

Education Act], and the Zakon of Radiodifuziji<br />

[Broadcasting Act]. The Montenegrin government<br />

on the other hand passed the Zakon o zabrani<br />

diskriminacije [Anti-discrimination Act] in 2010,<br />

which included sexual orientation and gender<br />

identity as protected classes, and they also passed<br />

the Zakon o radu [Labor Act] and the Zakon o<br />

medijima [Media Law], also geared toward increasing<br />

protection for sexual minorities.<br />

89 Ibid.<br />

family status and sexual orientation. 90 In its<br />

2012 Annual Report, the office reported a<br />

slight increase in complaints based on<br />

sexual orientation. 91 The slight yearly<br />

increases could suggest growing visibility<br />

and reliability of the institution as an<br />

effective instrument to channel<br />

discrimination complaints. 92<br />

The Commissioner for Protection<br />

of Equality in Serbia explained in its 2012<br />

Abridged Report that discrimination based<br />

on sexual orientation is still widespread in<br />

the country. 93 In 2012, there were only<br />

eight discrimination complaints on the<br />

90 Ombudsperson for Gender Equality, “Annual<br />

Report 2012,” Republic of Croatia (2013): 8,<br />

http://www.prs.hr/attachments/article/858/IZVJ<br />

ESCE%202012%20-%20ENG2-KB.pdf.<br />

91 Ibid., 10. There were 39 cases (10.6 %) in 2012<br />

compared to 16 cases (8.5%) in 2011, 12 cases<br />

(5.8%) in 2010, and 9 cases (4.4%) in 2009<br />

92 Ombudswoman for Gender Equality, “Annual<br />

Report for 2011,” Republic of Croatia (2012): 10,<br />

http://www.prs.hr/attachments/article/107/Summ<br />

ary%20of%20Annual%20Report%20for%202011%<br />

20web.pdf. In its 2011 Annual Report, the office<br />

mentioned that there was 22 criminal charges for<br />

hate crimes against LGBT people and 103<br />

misdemeanor charges against 62 people after the<br />

Split Pride in June 2011. Ibid. And using her<br />

authority under Anti-Discrimination Law, the<br />

Ombudswoman also intervened in four judicial<br />

proceedings in 2011 concerning discrimination<br />

claims based on sexual orientation: one case before<br />

the Municipal Court, one before the Administrative<br />

Court, and two before the Supreme Court. Ibid. In<br />

its 2011 report, the Ombudsperson for Gender<br />

Equality also made recommendations in a number<br />

of areas from education curriculum in public<br />

schools to the training of judges, prosecutors and<br />

law enforcement officials concerning discrimination<br />

issues against LGBT persons, and finally the report<br />

also asked for the development of a new legal<br />

framework that would appropriately protect LGBT<br />

persons in accordance with obligations vis-à-vis the<br />

EU and the Council of Europe. Ibid., 24.<br />

93 Commissioner for the Protection of Equality,<br />

“Abridged Report for 2012,” Republic of<br />

Serbia (2013): 43,<br />

http://www.ravnopravnost.gov.rs/jdownloads/files<br />

/engleski-web.pdf.<br />

16 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 16


asis of sexual orientation, accounting for<br />

only 2 percent of all claims. 94 Of the eight<br />

complaints, discrimination was found only<br />

in one case. 95 The report pointed out that<br />

such a small number suggests that cases<br />

were not being sufficiently reported. 96 The<br />

Protector of Human Rights and Freedoms<br />

of Montenegro handled 64 cases in 2012,<br />

and only three were discrimination claims<br />

based on sexual orientation and gender<br />

identity. 97 Although the 2012 Annual<br />

Report says that progress has been made in<br />

regards to the rights of LGBT persons, 98<br />

still per the same report, as of 2012, only<br />

one person in Montenegro had publicly<br />

declared himself as an LGBT person. 99<br />

However, the report also points out that<br />

adoption of the Strategy of Improvement<br />

of the Quality of Life of LGBT Persons<br />

2013-2018, which ensures freedom of<br />

assembly at public events like the Gay<br />

Pride along with a new law on same-sex<br />

unions would help contribute to the<br />

advancement of sexual minorities in<br />

Montenegro. 100<br />

94 Ibid., 15-16.<br />

95 Ibid., 44.<br />

96 Ibid. The report also expressed its concern over<br />

the consecutive cancellations of the Belgrade Pride<br />

in 2011 and 2012. Ibid., 43. Finally, the report<br />

concluded with recommendations for the education<br />

curriculum in public schools and training of law<br />

enforcement, judges, and prosecutors in regards to<br />

discrimination issues, among others. Ibid., 64-66.<br />

The report noted that the recommendation made in<br />

the previous year in regards to amending the<br />

Criminal Code to provide adequate punishment for<br />

hate crimes, including those based sexual<br />

orientation of the victim, had been implemented.<br />

Ibid., 64.<br />

97 Protector of Human Rights and Freedoms of<br />

Montenegro, “Annual Report 2012,” Government of<br />

Montenegro (2013): 82,<br />

http://www.ombudsman.co.me/docs/izvjestaji/19<br />

112013_Final_Izvjestaj.pdf.<br />

98 Ibid., 106.<br />

99 Ibid.<br />

100 Ibid.<br />

A brief review of the work<br />

implemented by these newly installed<br />

organizations shows that although they<br />

have only achieved modest success, these<br />

Western Balkan states are moving in the<br />

right direction with increasing political<br />

support. In fact, local politicians have been<br />

able to use EU conditionality to externalize<br />

the reasoning behind enacting unpopular<br />

anti-discrimination laws. Therefore, in<br />

many instances, EU conditionality has<br />

enabled local politicians to undertake risky<br />

political maneuvers that would have<br />

otherwise been impossible given the<br />

cultural context. 101<br />

Hence, although change could be<br />

more effective when it comes directly from<br />

a grassroots level, these supranationallyinspired<br />

organizations can and do play an<br />

important role in strengthening local civil<br />

society organizations by ensuring and<br />

advocating for their freedoms of assembly<br />

and speech. In addition, creating a<br />

supranational standard for equal rights is<br />

no de minimis feat either. The accompanying<br />

changes in the national legal codes will<br />

have a lasting impact and will also provide<br />

additional and alternative recourse at the<br />

supranational judicial bodies. In the end,<br />

having supranational anti-discrimination<br />

laws is of great significance.<br />

Yet some of these new laws don’t<br />

go as far as they should—like the Same-Sex<br />

Partnership Act in Croatia, which provides<br />

only three stipulations: “the right to<br />

common property, the right to be sustained<br />

by the partner, and prohibition of<br />

discrimination on the grounds of same-sex<br />

relationship and homosexual<br />

orientation.” 102 Nevertheless, it is<br />

uncontestably a move in the right direction<br />

in comparison to the previous legal regime<br />

that was in place.<br />

101 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 20.<br />

102 Ibid., 12.<br />

17 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 17


Finally, in the post-Yugoslav space,<br />

could EU conditionality be the actual<br />

culprit for the increased violence against<br />

sexual minorities? Not necessarily so—<br />

because such violent acts did peak up even<br />

in the absence of EU conditionality as a<br />

factor in other spaces, like same-sex<br />

marriage legislation in France. The<br />

common denominator in these cases seems<br />

to be increased visibility and public debates<br />

around issues of equal citizenship, and it is<br />

this common denominator that radicalizes<br />

and galvanizes the anti-gay movements,<br />

and that is regardless of the source of these<br />

debates—whether local, national or<br />

supranational. Same-sex marriage in France<br />

and EU conditionality requiring protection<br />

of sexual minorities in the former Yugoslav<br />

republics both essentially led to massive<br />

demonstrations, protests and violence<br />

against LGBT communities. Arguably, it is<br />

not the origin or the source of these<br />

debates that causes such unrest and<br />

detrimental effects on gay communities,<br />

but rather it is the very nature of these<br />

debates. Equal citizenship rights whether at<br />

the behest of national or supranational laws<br />

both tend to radicalize the opponents of<br />

such causes.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

The eternal debate in human rights<br />

scholarship is often fixated on the issue of<br />

cultural relativism. Inevitably, cultural<br />

perceptions of human dignity often varies<br />

from society to society, but the main<br />

question raised in this paper is that – can<br />

the law serve as an effective instrument to<br />

set a universal standard on some basic<br />

rights afforded to Mankind? More<br />

specifically, this paper looks to the<br />

European Union and posits whether the<br />

law of the supranational union can serve as<br />

a positive force in effecting change or is it a<br />

detriment in the advancement of sexual<br />

minority rights? Kahlina argues that the<br />

EU should not be confounded as an<br />

unambiguous liberator and that sexual<br />

minority groups have suffered<br />

consequences emanating from EUimposed<br />

legal changes. On the other hand,<br />

this paper presented a comparative and<br />

interpretive analysis, which argued that<br />

because similar backlashes occurred in the<br />

French context during the endogenous<br />

legalization process of same-sex marriage<br />

in 2013, causality for anti-gay sentiment is<br />

not necessarily because legal reform is<br />

exogenously promulgated by supranational<br />

bodies but is rather an expression of<br />

heteronormative preference in many<br />

societies.<br />

Strides toward augmenting<br />

citizenship rights for minorities often come<br />

at a cost and are usually part of a slow and<br />

incremental process. The battle for equal<br />

citizenship continues today in the EUacceding<br />

countries and across the world,<br />

from Uganda to the United States.<br />

Whether the movement for equal<br />

citizenship is spurred at a grassroots level<br />

or by an external supranational body does<br />

not necessarily determine the rate of<br />

acceptance of such causes. Despite being<br />

an imperfect tool, EU conditionality can<br />

actually serve as an effective instrument to<br />

broaden the scope of rights of sexual<br />

minorities in the acceding countries. In just<br />

the space of eleven years, the Croatian<br />

capital city of Zagreb has transformed:<br />

while the first Zagreb Pride in 2002 was<br />

mostly remembered for the violent protests<br />

against the marchers, numbering around<br />

200, 103 the 2013 Zagreb Pride had around<br />

15,000 participants, and it went on without<br />

disruption. 104<br />

103 “Croatian Gays Join First 'Pride' March,” BBC<br />

News.<br />

104 “ALDE Party Vice President joins Ljubljana<br />

Pride,” Alliance of Liberals and Democrats for Europe<br />

Party, last modified June 15, 2013,<br />

18 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 18


Although Kahlina does not<br />

unequivocally state that EU-inspired<br />

reforms in regards to LGBT rights has<br />

been completely counterproductive, she<br />

nevertheless argues against representing the<br />

EU as an “unambiguously liberating force”<br />

and that EU accession in fact facilitated<br />

turning “sexual citizenship into a contested<br />

terrain where the struggles between the<br />

competing visions of ‘Europeanness,’<br />

national identity, and tradition take<br />

place.” 105 While the second part of this<br />

conclusion could be quite plausible,<br />

especially in regards to the debate on<br />

‘Europeanness,’ national identity, and<br />

tradition being probably partly encouraged<br />

by the LGBT rights movement, however,<br />

the impressively liberating force of the EU<br />

accession process should nevertheless also<br />

be recognized. It is not as ambiguous as<br />

the author professes.<br />

The accession process has firstly<br />

put forward a legal guarantee for sexual<br />

minorities that enables them to utilize their<br />

rights to peaceful assembly and freedom of<br />

speech. Over the first decade of the new<br />

millennium, this legal right has been<br />

translated into tangible changes for sexual<br />

minorities in the acceding countries. By<br />

asking for guarantees of a safe space for<br />

the LGBT community, EU accession has<br />

contributed by giving to this group a<br />

chance to give expression to its rights and<br />

identity. Thus, the EU-inspired legal rights<br />

have created a gateway for both the antigay<br />

and LGBT groups to bring this cultural<br />

conflict into the sphere of public debate.<br />

Now Zagreb, Belgrade, Podgorica and<br />

others can speak, both for and against,<br />

openly about these issues just like they do<br />

in Paris. Before the EU-inspired reforms,<br />

these debates were largely taboo, which is<br />

http://www.aldeparty.eu/en/news/alde-party-vicepresident-joins-ljubljana-pride.<br />

105 Kahlina, “Contested Terrain of Sexual<br />

Citizenship,” 24.<br />

counterproductive to the LGBT rights<br />

movement. And from this perspective,<br />

even catalyzing protest against new laws is<br />

also a good thing in itself because it’s part<br />

of the public debate on something that was<br />

previously unmentionable.<br />

By allowing this issue to come out<br />

in public, even in the midst of violent<br />

protests, different stakeholders are given<br />

the opportunity to debate the merits and<br />

prioritization of the values that define their<br />

societies. What does it mean to be Serbian<br />

and European? Is this about a clash of<br />

values—is equal dignity, respect and rights<br />

of every human being, irrespective of one’s<br />

sexual orientation, exclusively a Western<br />

value or is it a universal human value? Like<br />

the Former Secretary of State Hillary<br />

Rodham Clinton once said: calling gay<br />

rights as such is by no means “creating new<br />

or special rights” for the LGBT people, it<br />

is only a way of “honoring rights that<br />

people always had.” 106 She went on to say<br />

that “[l]ike being a woman, like being a<br />

racial, religious, tribal, or ethnic minority,<br />

being LGBT does not make you less<br />

human. And that is why gay rights are<br />

human rights, and human rights are gay<br />

rights.” 107<br />

EU accession enables these<br />

societies to bring this kind of debate out in<br />

the open because in existing legal and<br />

social relations, inequality had already been<br />

institutionalized and unexamined. The law<br />

plays a unique role here as it makes an<br />

explicit and public promise that the<br />

legitimate authorities will act within<br />

particular boundaries 108 and allow this<br />

106 Hillary Rodham Clinton, Secretary of State,<br />

“Remarks in Recognition of International Human<br />

Rights Day,” U.S. Department of State, last modified<br />

December 6, 2011,<br />

http://www.state.gov/secretary/20092013clinton/r<br />

m/2011/12/178368.htm.<br />

107 Ibid.<br />

108 Holzhacker, “State-Sponsored Homophobia,” 5.<br />

19 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 19


debate to take place. As such, stakeholders<br />

in the EU-acceding states are given the<br />

opportunity to negotiate whether these<br />

legal reforms are consistent with their<br />

national values. Law reflects community<br />

morality, and the importance of change in<br />

law cannot be underestimated because it’s<br />

also a testament of the changing values in<br />

society, which here is concluded via a<br />

negotiation process that is guaranteed in<br />

the EU space. Hence, in that sense, EU<br />

accession has in fact been an awesome<br />

liberator by allowing sexual minority<br />

groups to bring this debate out in the open.<br />

If a country wants to be member of<br />

an institution, it has to follow certain rules.<br />

And thus imposing non-discrimination<br />

provisions as a condition of entry into<br />

exclusive economic partnerships, like the<br />

EU, can be an effective way to ensure<br />

equal citizenship across the membership.<br />

This is more effective than non-binding<br />

resolutions, conventions and charters on<br />

human rights because of the legal<br />

enforcement and remedies available within<br />

the EU-acceding states and at the<br />

supranational judicial level.<br />

Although not currently on the<br />

agenda, the question could ultimately be<br />

posed as to whether the international<br />

landscape would look any different if we<br />

impose human rights provisions as a<br />

condition of membership into vital<br />

economic organizations like the WTO,<br />

IMF or World Bank? Although such<br />

organizations pursue a wholly different<br />

aim, could requiring strict adherence to<br />

human rights provisions from members,<br />

with sanctioning mechanisms in place,<br />

actually change the world for the better? In<br />

fact, the World Bank is currently reviewing<br />

its “lending policies to make sure that no<br />

loan assists discrimination” and has<br />

currently put on hold a $90m loan to<br />

Uganda after the country enacted one of<br />

the most severe and cruel anti-gay laws. 109<br />

While many argue that the poor are the<br />

ones who ultimately suffer from such cuts<br />

and not the politicians, a more appropriate<br />

strategy is not to cut all aid but rather to<br />

redirect the funds to international aid<br />

agencies and local NGOs like Britain<br />

currently does. 110<br />

Attaching economic sanctions to<br />

human rights violations can send a very<br />

strong signal to the world community.<br />

Redirecting funds to local NGOs and<br />

international aid agencies can paralyze, or<br />

at the very least take some power away<br />

from, local governments that are engaging<br />

in the persecution of minority groups.<br />

Imposing non-discrimination requirements<br />

at a supranational level is already having an<br />

impact on the advancement of sexual<br />

citizenship in the EU. The challenge of this<br />

century is for our world leaders to make<br />

the bold linkage between human rights and<br />

membership in supranational economic<br />

organizations. After two world wars, the<br />

Universal Declaration of Human Rights<br />

(UDHR) was adopted– the world<br />

community was united in its resolve that<br />

everyone was entitled to the rights and<br />

freedoms in that declaration, irrespective of<br />

one’s belonging to a minority group.<br />

However, we see that the translation of the<br />

UDHR into actually securing the rights of<br />

minorities in member countries is not<br />

109 “The World Bank: Right Cause, Wrong Battle,”<br />

The Economist, last modified April 12, 2014,<br />

http://www.economist.com/news/leaders/216006<br />

84-why-world-banks-focus-gay-rights-misguidedright-cause-wrong-battle.<br />

110 Alex Whiting, “Western Donors Cut Aid to<br />

Uganda in Response to Anti-Gay Law,” Thomson<br />

Reuters Foundation, last modified February 26,<br />

2014, http://www.trust.org/item/20140226160032-<br />

td4jl/. In addition to the World Bank, the following<br />

countries, Denmark, The Netherlands, Norway,<br />

United States, Austria and Sweden, have also<br />

followed the same strategy by cutting or threatening<br />

to cut direct economic aid to the Ugandan<br />

government because of its anti-gay laws.<br />

20 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 20


necessarily effectual. But, the EU as an<br />

economic union, on the other hand, has<br />

succeeded not only in keeping Europe safe<br />

after two world wars, it has also actively<br />

augmented the rights of its citizens. Nondiscrimination<br />

on the basis of sexual<br />

orientation is de jure the current state of<br />

affairs in the EU member countries. It is<br />

this sort of economic union and<br />

interdependence that’s leading to a new<br />

order in world affairs. Rather than<br />

continually adopting human rights nonbinding<br />

resolutions, societies should maybe<br />

move toward an economic, social and legal<br />

belonging strategy, as magnificently<br />

employed by the EU.<br />

SÉHZAD M.<br />

SOOKLALL is a<br />

graduating law<br />

student at Yeshiva<br />

University Benjamin<br />

N. Cardozo School of<br />

Law and a concurrent<br />

Master of Arts in<br />

Politics candidate at<br />

New York University.<br />

Séhzad completed his<br />

first year law school<br />

curriculum at Tulane<br />

University after graduating summa cum laude<br />

from Louisiana State University in Baton Rouge<br />

with a Bachelor of Arts in Mass Communication<br />

and a minor in International Studies.<br />

Additionally, he also holds a Master of Public<br />

Administration from the LSU College of<br />

Business. Séhzad would like to thank the<br />

following people—foremost his parents,<br />

Sahejakoom and Farozia Sooklall; his American<br />

parents, John and Annette Douthat; his uncle,<br />

Kader Parahoo, and his professors and<br />

supervisors: Dr. Carole L. Jurkiewicz, Josephine<br />

Mason Ellis, Morgan Russell, Sheri P. Rosenberg,<br />

Julia Harrington Reddy, Kammae Owens, and<br />

Hafida Lahiouel. Finally, Séhzad would like to<br />

thank these very important people for their<br />

constant love, support, and friendship: Thomas<br />

Kyle Bridges, Kathlyn Van Buskirk, and Barbara<br />

Douthat Chatelain.<br />

21 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 21


Does Official<br />

Development Assistance<br />

Contribute to Long-<br />

Term Growth and<br />

Stability in Afghanistan?<br />

David Esmati<br />

Since 2001, the United States and the<br />

international community have pledged<br />

$90 billion towards reconstructing<br />

Afghanistan’s infrastructure, education<br />

system, healthcare,and public institutions.<br />

With more than half of the disbursed aid<br />

spent on military and peacekeeping<br />

operations, the $57 billion in official<br />

development assistance (ODA) already<br />

disbursed represents only a fraction of the $90<br />

billion promised. Although the international<br />

community has explicitly made economic<br />

development a priority, the use of disbursed<br />

aid for security purposes proves otherwise. In<br />

order to analyze the impact of the ODA<br />

pledged so far, this article seeks to address the<br />

question: Does official development assistance<br />

contribute to stable economic and political institutions<br />

that can sustain economic activity and long-term<br />

economic growth in Afghanistan?<br />

Donor countries reassure the<br />

international community that their aid will<br />

positively impact the lives of millions of<br />

Afghans. According to the report released by<br />

the International Crisis Group, “[a]ccess to<br />

education has improved, with 6.2 million<br />

children attending school, 85 percent of all<br />

Afghans now have access to some form of<br />

healthcare, compared to 9 percent in 2002.” 1<br />

1 “Human Rights in Afghanistan,” Aid and Conflict in<br />

Afghanistan 210 (2011), The International Crisis<br />

Group, August 4, 2011, accessed October 13, 2013.<br />

However, the bulk of this aid is spent on<br />

security operations: the United States alone is<br />

spending $36 billion a year on security-related<br />

issues, resulting in $57 received per capita per<br />

Afghan citizen. 2 By relying on NGOs and<br />

foreign contractor companies, the donor<br />

community does not directly disburse ODA<br />

to the central government of Afghanistan, but<br />

rather directs the bulk of the aid to private<br />

contractors. Consequently, the Afghan people<br />

are not the beneficiaries of ODA. Instead,<br />

NGOs and contractors conducting projects<br />

are utilized on behalf of foreign donors. As a<br />

result, the pledged aid does not address the<br />

long-term development of Afghanistan’s<br />

economy. It does not address the lack of<br />

public institutions and the enforcement of the<br />

rule of law. The international community has<br />

failed to “adequately support state institutions<br />

such as parliament and the judiciary, that<br />

could provide a check on the power of the<br />

executive.” 3 ODA provided directly to<br />

domestic public institutions would lead to<br />

better development outcomes in Afghanistan.<br />

Long-term economic growth is a realistic<br />

outcome only when ODA ownership shifts<br />

from that of the recipient to the host country.<br />

The technical assistance provided by the<br />

international community coupled with state<br />

ownership of ODA contributes to an<br />

educated labor force in the long-term.<br />

http://www.crisisgroup.org/en/regions/asia/southasia<br />

/afghanistan/210aid-and-conflict-in-afghanistan.aspx.<br />

2 Matt Waldman, “Falling Short: Aid Effectiveness in<br />

Afghanistan,” Oxfam, March 2008, accessed on<br />

October 13, 2013.<br />

https://www.oxfam.org/sites/www.oxfam.org/files/A<br />

CBAR_aid_effectiveness_paper_0803.pdf.<br />

3 “Human Rights in Afghanistan,” The International<br />

Crisis Group.<br />

22 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 22


UNDERSTANDING OFFICIAL<br />

DEVELOPMENT ASSISTANCE<br />

There is a lack of consensus on the<br />

role of official development assistance.<br />

Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson, in<br />

Economic Backwardness in Political Review, stress<br />

that development aid primarily benefits the<br />

political elite, those individuals close to the<br />

governing body. 4 These individuals are ready<br />

to incur any costs to stay in power and<br />

sometimes “may block technological and<br />

institutional development” to do so. 5 This<br />

argument emphasizes the “political<br />

replacement effect,” in which those in power<br />

or close to the governing body want to<br />

maintain the status quo due to the<br />

destabilization of the existing system. 6 The<br />

fear of losing power forces the ruling class to<br />

decide whether they will adopt technologies<br />

and institutional changes that would<br />

undermine their control or not. Similarly, their<br />

model suggests that interest groups or<br />

monopolists seek to protect their interests by<br />

taking advantage of weak government<br />

institutions, and a lack of rule of law<br />

enforcement.<br />

Claudia R. Williamson highlights, in<br />

Exploring the Failure of Foreign Aid: The Role of<br />

Incentives and Information, the purpose of foreign<br />

aid and its implications for both the donor<br />

and the receiving state. She points out that<br />

“despite a large amount of time and resources<br />

devoted to development assistance, two<br />

competing theories have emerged: public<br />

interest versus the public choice perspective.” 7<br />

4 Daron Acemoglu, and James A. Robinson,<br />

“Economic Backwardness in Political Perspective,”<br />

American Political Science Review, February 2006, accessed<br />

on October 13, 2014.<br />

http%3A%2F%2Feconomics.mit.edu%2Ffiles%2F447<br />

1.<br />

5 Ibid.<br />

6 Ibid.<br />

7 Claudia R. Williamson, “Exploring the Failure of<br />

Foreign Aid: The Role of Incentives and Information,”<br />

The Review of Austrian Economics 23, no. 1 (2010),<br />

accessed October 13, 2013.<br />

Public interest theory, “argues that foreign aid<br />

is necessary to fill a financing or investment<br />

gap, and this will in turn lift countries out of a<br />

so-called poverty trap.” 8 The public choice<br />

theory “contends that foreign aid is ineffective<br />

and possibly damaging to recipient<br />

countries.” 9 The public interest theory holds<br />

that those involved with the distribution of<br />

aid seek to advance their narrow institutional<br />

interests. Williamson highlights three forms of<br />

aid channels that result from such special<br />

interest incentives. “Tied aid” is a regimen<br />

that “requires recipients to purchase a certain<br />

percentage of goods from the donor country,<br />

often overcharging recipients from being able<br />

to purchase goods cheaper elsewhere.” 10 For<br />

the U.S., this means about 75% of all aid<br />

spending has to go to back to U.S. companies.<br />

Food aid is another channel that<br />

Williamson highlights as a way for donors to<br />

benefit from the exchange at the expense of<br />

the recipients. The aid is “mainly in-kind<br />

provision of foods that typically could be<br />

purchased much cheaper in recipient local<br />

markets.” 11 As for technical assistance, she<br />

holds that it is often not beneficial for the<br />

host country because “donors usually require<br />

these technicians to be from the donor<br />

country.” 12 Instead of training the local and<br />

national capacity of the developing country,<br />

the recipient of the aid must make do with<br />

consultants who may or may not understand<br />

the political and cultural landscape of the<br />

region. And should the programs fail to meet<br />

their goals, a donor may act “as a budget<br />

maximizing bureaucracy calling for increases<br />

in foreign aid in order to increase its own<br />

budget and thus increase its agency” rather<br />

than adjust the programs. 13<br />

http://dri.fas.nyu.edu/docs/IO/12361/WilliamsonRA<br />

EAid.pdf.<br />

8 Ibid.<br />

9 Ibid.<br />

10 Ibid., 5.<br />

11 Ibid.<br />

12 Ibid.<br />

13 Ibid.<br />

23 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 23


Simply redirecting the aid to domestic<br />

institutions may not solve the problem.<br />

Actors within the recipient country, like the<br />

NGOs and special interest groups from the<br />

international arena, may have their own<br />

political agendas. Much of the disbursed aid<br />

goes to corrupt institutions. “Under the guise<br />

of official development assistance,” foreign<br />

aid “is aiding the ability of dictators to remain<br />

in power.” 14 As a result, the Good Samaritan<br />

dilemma emerges, in which the “recipients<br />

believe that future poverty will increase the<br />

likelihood of more foreign aid, aid could<br />

actually worsen incentives to invest” while<br />

“citizens now face an even stronger incentive<br />

to consume and become dependent on the<br />

donors.” 15 Accordingly, foreign aid has little<br />

to no effect on infrastructure and long-term<br />

development efforts. Acemoglu, Robinson,<br />

and Williamson all imply that foreign aid<br />

compromises state’s institutions and the rule<br />

of law. Since the involvement of foreign aid<br />

introduces external actors in the form of<br />

consultants and special interest groups, the<br />

competing interests of multiple actors does<br />

not allow for the state to follow policies that<br />

best address the economic needs of the<br />

people and the state as a whole.<br />

On the other hand, NGOs and<br />

international organizations have indeed<br />

contributed significantly to the development<br />

of Afghanistan. This was made possible in<br />

part by the Paris Declaration on Aid<br />

Effectiveness. It is a practical, action-oriented<br />

roadmap to improve the quality of aid and its<br />

impact on development. It ensures that<br />

recipient countries utilize their own strategies<br />

to better outline their needs, whilst improving<br />

the overall quality of public institutions. With<br />

the help of NGOs and other international<br />

organizations that adhere to the Paris<br />

Declaration principles, developing countries<br />

have been able to better coordinate efforts to<br />

avoid duplicating services. Less developed<br />

14 Ibid., 6.<br />

15 Ibid., 6.<br />

countries such as Afghanistan have been able<br />

to increase their standard of living and<br />

improve national healthcare partly due to such<br />

efforts.<br />

Nonetheless, in his book The End of<br />

Poverty, Jeffrey Sachs explains that the reason<br />

certain countries are rich and others are poor<br />

is because of multitude of barriers preventing<br />

the poor from climbing the economic<br />

ladder. 16 These barriers include: poverty and<br />

fiscal traps, physical geography, weak<br />

institutions and governance failure, cultural<br />

and trade barriers, lack of innovation, and the<br />

demographic trap. All of these factors<br />

demonstrate the intense complexity of<br />

obstacles that threaten to preclude economic<br />

development efforts in the world’s poorest<br />

countries. This further delineates the<br />

importance—but also the limits—of foreign<br />

aid. The proper implementation of<br />

development aid initiatives is of critical<br />

importance when domestic institutions and<br />

NGOs alike seek to navigate the abovereferenced<br />

challenges to socioeconomic<br />

development in poor countries.<br />

THE FRAMEWORK OF AID TO<br />

AFGHANISTAN<br />

With multiple channels of aid opening<br />

up to assist the Afghan Interim Authority in<br />

winter 2001, the international community, at<br />

the January 2002 Conference on the<br />

Reconstruction of Afghanistan in Tokyo,<br />

“pledged more than $4.5 billion in aid for the<br />

next five years, increasing to $9.7 billion for<br />

2001-2003.” 17<br />

16 Jeffrey Sachs, The End of Poverty: Economic Possibilities<br />

for Our Time (New York: Penguin, 2005).<br />

17 “Human Rights in Afghanistan,” The International<br />

Crisis Group.<br />

24 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 24


Subsequently, in April 2004 at the<br />

Berlin Conference, “the international<br />

community increased its commitment to $8.2<br />

billion over three years.” 18 At the same time,<br />

U.S. non-military pledges rose from $250<br />

million in FY2003 to $720 million in<br />

FY2004. 19 At the 2006 London Conference in<br />

2006, donor countries pledged a further $10.5<br />

billion, and then $21 billion at the Paris<br />

Conference two years later. 20 Since 2002, the<br />

external assistance flowing into Afghanistan<br />

increased exponentially but without proper<br />

justification of how and where the ODA was<br />

needed and spent. The rise in ODA as a<br />

percentage of Afghanistan’s GDP conveyed<br />

the notion that the Afghan Central<br />

Government had successfully implemented<br />

programs to address the economic challenges.<br />

However, the overall amount of ODA<br />

given to Afghanistan has failed to distinguish<br />

between humanitarian, rehabilitation, and<br />

reconstruction needs. “[A]s a result, by 2006,<br />

roughly one-third of funds were directed<br />

towards humanitarian assistance rather than<br />

reconstruction or development projects that<br />

would have helped rebuild and revive a<br />

18 Ibid.<br />

19 Ibid.<br />

20 Ibid.<br />

devastated infrastructure and economy and<br />

the state’s capacity to deliver basic services.” 21<br />

And since the U.S. led the international<br />

community in providing both military and<br />

humanitarian or economic assistance, most of<br />

the aid was channeled through local proxies.<br />

These proxies included local warlords, special<br />

interest groups, and NGOs with connections<br />

to the inner circle of the Afghan presidential<br />

office. By concentrating power into the hands<br />

of these few, political figures received the aid<br />

and then channeled it to the most politically<br />

rewarding destinations.<br />

Moreover, the establishment of nonmilitary<br />

structures to channel funds<br />

throughout the 34 provinces of Afghanistan<br />

has created a loophole in which contractors<br />

and government officials have been able to<br />

operate without proper oversight from the<br />

international community. Since one of the<br />

primary objectives of international assistance<br />

is to make sure Afghanistan does not unravel<br />

into a series of fiefdoms, the conjoining of<br />

military and humanitarian assistance led to the<br />

creation of the Provincial Reconstruction<br />

Teams (PRT). The PRT program was<br />

established to “assist the Islamic Republic of<br />

Afghanistan to extend its authority in order to<br />

facilitate the development of a stable and<br />

secure environment in the identified area of<br />

operation, and enable Security Sector Reform<br />

and reconstruction efforts.” 22 The funding of<br />

these teams is solely up to its eleven donor<br />

countries. Therefore, the level of coordination<br />

between the Afghan government and its<br />

donors is often weak and heavily influenced<br />

by the political relationships with the donor<br />

country. Coupled with weak oversight, a<br />

majority of the PRT projects have produced<br />

poor results due to subcontracting or the<br />

transfer of large-scale projects to unqualified<br />

individuals. Because of this, the PRTs “have<br />

slowed the emergence and development of<br />

state institutions at local level, which<br />

21 Ibid.<br />

22 Ibid.<br />

25 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 25


jeopardizes the broader prospects for medium<br />

to long term state-building.” 23<br />

This also “hinders efforts to increase<br />

Afghan ownership of the development<br />

process,” when ownership of aid plays a key<br />

role in the long-term economic growth of a<br />

state. Stated as the central element of the Paris<br />

Declaration on Aid Effectiveness, “national<br />

ownership is critical to achieving development<br />

results.” 24 Hence, the Afghan government<br />

stresses the ownership of ODA, yet more<br />

than “two-thirds of foreign assistance<br />

bypasses the Afghan government.” 25 One<br />

consequence of this lack of ownership is that<br />

it “limits ability of ministries to recruit and<br />

retain qualified staff as they are attracted by<br />

higher salaries with donors or donor-funded<br />

projects.” 26 With majority of the funds being<br />

channeled through the external budget,<br />

instead of the “core” budget, the Afghan<br />

national government cannot build the human<br />

capacity needed to strengthen and maintain<br />

public institutions.<br />

MISUSE OF AID BY BOTH DONORS<br />

AND RECIPIENTS<br />

At the state level, international<br />

assistance to Afghanistan has yet to produce<br />

sustainable economic results. Lack of<br />

government accountability is still a major<br />

concern for citizens and international NGOs.<br />

According to an Integrity Watch Afghanistan<br />

(IWA) survey, “one in seven adults paid a<br />

bribe in 2010, 28 percent were to obtain a<br />

public service, including health and<br />

education.” 27 At the international level, NGOs<br />

and private contractor workers have taken<br />

advantage of weak regulatory institutions and<br />

a lack of legal enforcement. They have funded<br />

23 Waldman, “Falling Short: Aid Effectiveness in<br />

Afghanistan.”<br />

24 Ibid.<br />

25 Ibid.<br />

26 Ibid.<br />

27 “Human Rights in Afghanistan,” The International<br />

Crisis Group.<br />

many state-building projects that are not<br />

properly assessed or do not meet state<br />

requirements. With the addition of high<br />

oversight budgets, the lack of oversight<br />

resulted in contract workers receiving<br />

disproportionately high salaries. For example,<br />

282 foreign advisors (including 120<br />

contractors) within the Afghan Interior<br />

Ministry are “absorbing a total of $36 million<br />

a year,” and “international staff reportedly<br />

outnumber the Afghans they advise by 45 to<br />

fourteen” in the ministry’s logistics arm. 28<br />

There is a self-perpetuating cycle here.<br />

Donor countries rely heavily on private<br />

contractors and NGOs to implement the<br />

majority of the ODA. In return, these groups<br />

exercise oversight of donor-funded projects<br />

since the Afghan government lacks the<br />

capacity to monitor all development<br />

assistance. Between 2007 and 2009, “USAID<br />

obligated 53 percent of its construction funds<br />

($2 billion of $3.8 billion)” to just two<br />

American contractors: the Louis Berger<br />

Group and Development Alternatives. 29 The<br />

overcharging and misuse of billions of dollars<br />

in administrative fees and personnel<br />

compensation has failed to produce public<br />

benefits and strengthen the rule of law. These<br />

projects, initially given to international<br />

construction firms have been subcontracted<br />

to either Afghan or other private firms in<br />

return for a percentage of the overall budget.<br />

In some large contracts, there were multiple<br />

layers of subcontractors, in each case taking a<br />

10-20% profit.<br />

Contractors and NGOs requiring<br />

substantial administrative fees coupled with<br />

billions of dollars in subcontracting profits are<br />

wasting much of the ODA requisitioned to<br />

complete national projects throughout<br />

Afghanistan. The Kabul Bank fraud, for<br />

example, highlights the “susceptibility of<br />

international assistance and the need for<br />

vigilant oversight in a corrupt and insecure<br />

28 Ibid.<br />

29 Ibid.<br />

26 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 26


environment.” 30 Providing both logistical and<br />

technical assistance to USAID, Deloitte<br />

Consulting was the lead organization in<br />

capacity building and supervision at<br />

Afghanistan’s Central Bank. However,<br />

Deloitte “failed to warn authorities” about the<br />

rampant corruption with the Kabul Bank. 31<br />

The reconstruction of the Khair Khana<br />

maternity hospital in Kabul is a striking<br />

example of the misuse of aid. In order to<br />

double the hospital’s capacity, the Italian<br />

government contracted UNFPA with $2.2<br />

million for the work. It was first<br />

subcontracted to the UN Office for Project<br />

Services (UNOPS), then an Italian contractor,<br />

and, finally, a local construction firm. This<br />

arrangement ultimately consumed about half<br />

of the project’s finances, and what was left<br />

was spent on poor quality building materials<br />

that posed a health hazard. 32 A further<br />

example of this sort of problem is the<br />

[continued on page ]<br />

30 Ibid.<br />

31 Ibid.<br />

32 Waldman, “Falling Short: Aid Effectiveness in<br />

Afghanistan.”<br />

27 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 27


Total planned and committed government and donor spending per capita, per province in<br />

2007<br />

Data Source: Oxfam. Afghan Ministry of Finance<br />

Completed, ongoing, planned and funded PRT spending per capita, per province<br />

Data Source: Oxfam. ISAF, May 2007<br />

28 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 28


construction of a short stretch of the road in<br />

the province of Badakhshan, linking the town<br />

center to the area airstrip. In an unfortunately<br />

familiar pattern, the road “was subcontracted<br />

to a private company by USAID for just<br />

under half a million dollars,” then “again<br />

subcontracted to an Afghan private<br />

construction company for a cost of just<br />

$250,000.” 33<br />

AFGHANISTAN CASE STUDY<br />

The disbursement of aid plays a vital role in<br />

impacting the lives of the Afghan people. In<br />

order to analyze whether official development<br />

assistance contributed to the economic<br />

growth throughout the provinces of<br />

Afghanistan, the study will assess the Afghan<br />

central government’s implementation of<br />

ODA separately from the international donor<br />

community.<br />

The difference in the amount of<br />

spending per capita throughout the provinces,<br />

as illustrated in both of the charts above,<br />

signifies the difference between the Afghan<br />

government and the international<br />

communities’ priorities in the provinces that<br />

need the most assistance. The security<br />

spending does not significantly help because it<br />

is spent in ways that only exacerbate<br />

unaccountability and donor preferences over<br />

local needs and rule of law. The amount of<br />

spending per capita by the PRTs in each of<br />

the 34 provinces, primarily led by<br />

international donors and private contractors,<br />

takes into account military and administrative<br />

costs for the total amount of spending.<br />

The regional disparity in ODA shows<br />

that the international community is looking to<br />

fund provinces that are the least militarily<br />

secure in the short term. The main focus of<br />

the PRTs and international assistance is in the<br />

south and southeast regions of Afghanistan,<br />

33 Ibid.<br />

areas where the Taliban’s insurgency is<br />

strongest. Provinces with the smallest<br />

populations, such as Badghis and Uruzgan,<br />

received the highest amount of PRT<br />

assistance. Meanwhile, the central<br />

government’s core budget spending mainly<br />

focuses on centralizing power in the<br />

provinces closest to Kabul. Although they<br />

emphasize development efforts in areas that<br />

are the least secure, they do not neglect<br />

provinces in the northern parts of the country<br />

to the same degree as international donors do.<br />

For example, the Afghan national government<br />

spent more in the provinces of Faryab and<br />

Badakhshan, installing irrigation systems and<br />

building agriculture infrastructure to help the<br />

local farmers of the region. The PRTs and the<br />

international community spent well below $50<br />

per capita in the same provinces. The<br />

northern provinces of Afghanistan have fertile<br />

soil and a climate more suitable for<br />

agriculture. By providing farmers the technical<br />

aid they need to maintain their crops yearround,<br />

the Afghan government’s technical<br />

assistance encourages the growth of the<br />

agriculture sector of the economy.<br />

The emphasis on quick impact<br />

projects led by the PRTs has not been<br />

accompanied by a strengthening of the<br />

Afghan government’s capacity to sustain the<br />

goals of these projects over time. The limited<br />

provincial development funds “undercut the<br />

government’s credibility, since districts or<br />

provinces might attract aid but have no funds<br />

to sustain projects once they are transferred to<br />

local authorities,” leading to the perception<br />

among Afghans that these projects are just<br />

another tool being used by external forces to<br />

impose control over them. 34 The multiple<br />

channels of funding are creating a rift between<br />

the provinces and the central government,<br />

both fiscally and ideologically. Shortsighted<br />

34 “Human Rights in Afghanistan,” The International<br />

Crisis Group.<br />

29 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 29


development efforts have been difficult to<br />

sustain due to the PRTs and international<br />

communities’ biased funding mechanisms.<br />

Consequently, once the drawdown of foreign<br />

contractors, advisors, and security personnel<br />

began in December of 2014, provincial<br />

leaders lacked adequate funding to maintain<br />

development projects. The lack of skilled<br />

native talent overall, and within government<br />

offices in particular, due to the<br />

overrepresentation of foreigners and skewed<br />

hiring practices of locals is contribution to the<br />

unraveling of more than ten years of ODA to<br />

Afghanistan.<br />

FINDINGS AND CONCLUSION<br />

After spending $57 billion on<br />

humanitarian assistance over the past fourteen<br />

years in Afghanistan, the international<br />

community is looking for answers as to why<br />

Afghanistan’s dependence on aid has not<br />

fallen at a rate the World Bank and the<br />

international donor community had hoped it<br />

would. Afghanistan now more than ever,<br />

needs economic and technical assistance to<br />

ensure that it does not collapse into the same<br />

state it was a decade ago. The Taliban have<br />

once again started to rise in the southern<br />

provinces of Afghanistan. Furthermore, it is<br />

crucial to note that since the international<br />

community led the majority of the<br />

development efforts, the infrastructure has<br />

been built for their own security purposes, not<br />

civil reconstruction. As the younger<br />

generation of Afghans start to take advantage<br />

of the greatly expanded education system, the<br />

need for a coherent economic development<br />

effort is vital to reduce high unemployment.<br />

In the case of Afghanistan,<br />

Williamson’s “public choice perspective” can<br />

best describe the effort to rebuild<br />

Afghanistan’s weak and dependent economy.<br />

Weak rule of law and the lack of<br />

accountability have created an environment<br />

for private contractors and NGOs to reap<br />

millions of dollars in profits from ODA<br />

without creating sustainable infrastructure. As<br />

a result, national public works projects that<br />

can benefit millions of Afghans have been<br />

poorly managed and in some cases have not<br />

even been implemented. Weak oversight<br />

coupled with high corruption have led to<br />

backdoor deals between the political elite and<br />

the international donor community,<br />

marginalizing Afghan citizens in dire need of<br />

humanitarian assistance. The Karzai<br />

Administration has been under scrutiny by the<br />

World Bank, IMF, and the United States for<br />

taking advantage of Afghanistan’s weak<br />

financial regulatory bodies by using millions<br />

of dollars of foreign aid for personal gains. 35<br />

Ownership of ODA plays a significant<br />

role in the long-term economic growth of<br />

Afghanistan. Since most of the aid bypasses<br />

the Afghan government and is directly<br />

disbursed to private firms and NGOs,<br />

provincial governments and the central<br />

administration cannot build the capacity they<br />

need to operate with the proper funding to<br />

attract and train native talent. Instead of using<br />

contractors and NGOs, both the Afghan<br />

government and international aid agencies<br />

must take greater advantage of the local talent,<br />

and work to cultivate it. By doing so, national<br />

projects will be far more effective and<br />

sustainable because the morale of the people<br />

will change from that of being a recipient state<br />

to that of a developing state.<br />

The ODA given to Afghanistan has<br />

been utilized for short-term gains in security<br />

and economic development: as a result,<br />

neither has been advanced in the long run.<br />

Long-term security and economic growth in<br />

Afghanistan are most likely to occur when the<br />

international community accepts that the<br />

Afghan people have a greater part to play in<br />

development efforts.<br />

35 James Risen, “Karzai’s Kin Use Ties to Gain Power<br />

in Afghanistan,” The New York Times, October 5, 2010,<br />

accessed on October 13, 2013.<br />

http://www.nytimes.com/2010/10/06/world/asia/06<br />

karzai.html?pagewanted=all&_r=0.<br />

30 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 30


DAVID ESMATI is a<br />

second year M.A.<br />

student in International<br />

Relations. He earned his<br />

B.A. degree in<br />

International Relations<br />

Honors from the Wilf<br />

Family Department of<br />

Politics at New York<br />

University. He is interested in international security<br />

issues, Afghanistan-Pakistan, sustainable<br />

development, financing for development and postconflict<br />

recovery. His past work experience in<br />

related fields includes work with The Permanent<br />

Mission of Afghanistan to the United Nations, The<br />

United States Mission to the United Nations, NGOs<br />

and think tanks.<br />

31 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 31


From Operation Serval<br />

to Barkhane<br />

Understanding France’s<br />

Increased Involvement in<br />

Africa in the Context of<br />

Françafrique and Postcolonialism<br />

Carmen Cuesta Roca<br />

François Hollande did not enter office<br />

amid expectations that he would<br />

become a foreign policy president.<br />

His 2012 presidential campaign carefully<br />

focused on domestic issues. Much like<br />

Nicolas Sarkozy and many of his<br />

predecessors, Hollande had declared, “I will<br />

break away from Françafrique by proposing a<br />

relationship based on equality, trust, and<br />

solidarity.” 1 After his election on May 6,<br />

2012, Hollande took steps to fulfill this<br />

promise. He became the first president of<br />

the Fifth Republic not to have an “Africa<br />

cell” 2 and appointed as his Africa adviser<br />

Hélène Le Gal, a diplomat with previous<br />

experience in East Africa and far removed<br />

from the old networks of France’s former<br />

colonies.<br />

Fast forward to January 2013. Four<br />

thousand French troops were deployed to<br />

Mali as part of Operation Serval, following<br />

the United Nations Security Council<br />

Resolution 2085 in December 2012 and an<br />

official request from the Malian interim<br />

government for French assistance. 3 That<br />

1 “Engagement 58,” Parti Socialiste, February 2, 2012,<br />

accessed December 1, 2014, http://www.partisocialiste.fr/articles/engagement-58.<br />

2 Founded during the Charles de Gaulle<br />

administration, this is a location where the President<br />

and his advisors take decisions on military support<br />

for African countries or for the ruling governments.<br />

3 United Nations, “Security Council Authorizes<br />

Deployment of African-Led International Support<br />

Mission in Mali for Initial Year-Long Period<br />

Meetings Coverage and Press Releases,” UN News<br />

same year, Hollande sent French troops to<br />

the Central African Republic (CAR) to curb<br />

ethno-religious warfare. During a visit to<br />

three African nations in the summer of<br />

2014, the French president announced<br />

Operation Barkhane, a reorganization of<br />

troops in the region into a counter-terrorism<br />

force of 3,000 soldiers.<br />

In light of this, what is one to make<br />

of Hollande’s promise to break with<br />

tradition concerning France’s African<br />

policy? To what extent has he actively<br />

pursued the fulfillment of this promise, and<br />

does continued French involvement in<br />

Africa constitute success or failure in this<br />

regard? France has a complex relationship<br />

with Africa, and these ties cannot be easily<br />

cut. This paper does not seek to provide a<br />

critique of President Hollande’s policy<br />

toward France’s former African colonies.<br />

Rather, it uses the current president’s<br />

decisions and behavior to explain why<br />

France will not be able to distance itself<br />

from its former colonies anytime soon.<br />

It is first necessary to outline a brief<br />

history of France’s involvement in Africa,<br />

with an emphasis on the exclusivity of<br />

France’s relationship with its former<br />

colonies and the period of “decolonization.”<br />

Interpretations of the term Françafrique (a<br />

French word used to described the special<br />

relationship between France and Africa) will<br />

be assessed, with particular attention paid to<br />

its neocolonial connotations, as well as an<br />

assessment of its utility and relevance as a<br />

tool of analysis. With this in mind, an<br />

examination of the French intervention in<br />

Mali will follow, with a focus on the<br />

Françafrique debate that has surrounded the<br />

conflict. Does the French intervention in<br />

Mali constitute change or continuity in<br />

terms of France’s colonial past? Why has<br />

this intervention, unlike others, been<br />

received with such popular support in<br />

France and Mali alike? The recent<br />

announcement of Operation Barkhane has<br />

also raised many questions concerning<br />

France’s involvement in Africa. This paper<br />

Center, December 20, 2012.<br />

www.un.org/press/en/2012/sc10870.doc.htm.<br />

32 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 32


will analyze different interpretations of this<br />

operation, while highlighting a fundamental<br />

aspect of the relationship between France<br />

and her former colonies: debt. In assessing<br />

Hollande’s decisions on African policy since<br />

his election in 2012, this paper examines<br />

France’s special relationship with its former<br />

colonies and explores the reasons why it<br />

continues to be difficult for France to break<br />

away from a Françafrique-style relationship<br />

with its colonies.<br />

A BRIEF HISTORY OF FRANCE IN<br />

AFRICA<br />

Historically, France has deep<br />

economic and political relations with Africa<br />

that date back to the 17 th Century. A<br />

distinction can be made between the First<br />

colonial empire, which had been mostly lost<br />

by 1814, and the Second colonial empire,<br />

whose beginning and end are marked by the<br />

takeover and independence of Algeria in<br />

1830 and 1862, respectively. This division is<br />

made because by 1814 France had lost most<br />

of the colonies gained in earlier years. The<br />

Berlin Conference of 1884 marked the<br />

beginning of organized conquest of the<br />

region, and aimed at regulating European<br />

colonization and trade in Africa. The<br />

federation of French West Africa (Afrique<br />

occidentale francaise) was established in 1904,<br />

and soon after in 1910, the federation of<br />

French Equatorial Africa (Afrique équatoriale<br />

francaise) was created. These federations<br />

grouped a number of French colonies<br />

together under the same authority in an<br />

effort to coordinate French colonization on<br />

the African continent. Countries today that<br />

were affected by this re-organization<br />

include: Benin, Burkina Faso, Cameroon,<br />

Central African Republic, Chad, Congo,<br />

Cote d’Ivoire, Gabon, Guinea, Libya, Mali,<br />

Mauritania, Niger, Senegal, and Togo.<br />

It is important to note that France’s<br />

involvement with its colonies was very<br />

different from other European powers’<br />

involvement in Africa. Britain’s colonial<br />

policy was primarily based on economic<br />

exploitation of its colonies, but France had a<br />

distinct mission. Metropolitan France<br />

additionally pursued a cultural and political<br />

assimilation policy that ignored regional<br />

cultures. This was done in a bid to enhance<br />

France’s international influence by<br />

extending to Africa the French values of<br />

human rights. This is the defining notion of<br />

France’s unique relationship with its<br />

colonies: “The British saw its colonies as<br />

foreign lands, the French saw them as a part<br />

of France, therefore France imposed its<br />

culture on Africa.” 4 This distinction still<br />

lingers today, and it adds a layer of<br />

complexity to the relationship between<br />

France and her former African colonies.<br />

The Brazzaville Conference of 1944<br />

marked a pivotal point in this relationship.<br />

Held in the capital of French Equatorial<br />

Africa, the conference assembled many<br />

prominent African leaders to discuss the<br />

revision of France’s relationship with its<br />

colonies. Many view this erroneously as the<br />

beginning of decolonization, when the<br />

reality is that, for Charles de Gaulle and<br />

other leading officials, the “aim of the<br />

conference was, on the contrary, to<br />

consolidate the colonial system definitively<br />

by renovating it.” 5 Even at this point,<br />

however, the idea of independence for<br />

African states was rejected among the<br />

French. As De Gaulle stated, “The aims of<br />

France's civilizing mission preclude any<br />

thought of autonomy or any possibility of<br />

development outside the French empire.<br />

Self-government must be rejected—even in<br />

the more distant future.” 6<br />

Yet, from the 1950s to the 1970s,<br />

independence became a reality for many<br />

French colonies. Many of these<br />

independences were achieved around the<br />

same time as each other and without<br />

4 Abdurrahim Siradag, “Understanding French<br />

Foreign and Security Policy towards Africa:<br />

Pragmatism or Altruism”, Afro Eurasian Studies, 3, no.<br />

1 (<strong>Spring</strong> 2014): 100.<br />

5 Yves Person, “French West Africa and<br />

Decolonization,” in The Transfer of Power in Africa:<br />

Decolonization, 1940-1960, ed. Prosser Gifford and<br />

Louis William Roger (New Haven: Yale University<br />

Press, 1982), 144.<br />

6 Donald A. Low, Britain and Indian Nationalism: The<br />

Imprint of Ambiguity 1929-1942, (Cambridge:<br />

Cambridge University Press, 1997), 16.<br />

33 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 33


considerable violence (with the exception of<br />

Cameroon). As such, France has continued<br />

to maintain its economic and political<br />

relations with its former colonies.<br />

Importantly, France has a special strategic<br />

security partnership with the African<br />

countries. At the time of independence, the<br />

French government created African national<br />

armies that would serve as branches of the<br />

French army overseas. 7 It was in this<br />

context that a number of bilateral security<br />

agreements were signed with each newly<br />

independent state: between 1960 and 1993,<br />

two-dozen agreements were signed between<br />

France and most of her former colonies. 8<br />

France has intervened militarily in Africa<br />

more than 50 times since 1960. 9<br />

Two of these interventions,<br />

Operation Serval and Operation Barkhane,<br />

require further investigation. Serval refers to<br />

a 2013 operation in which France<br />

intervened in Mali following the country’s<br />

request for assistance in the ousting of<br />

Islamic militants. Barkhane is France’s latest<br />

military endeavor in Africa, another<br />

counter-terrorist operation stretching from<br />

Mauritania to Chad that aims at limiting the<br />

mobility of jihadists in the region. The<br />

particularities of French colonial history in<br />

Central and West Africa lay the foundation<br />

for a unique relationship between France<br />

and its former African colonies. This helps<br />

explain why France still has such a<br />

connection to Africa, while other former<br />

colonial powers do not.<br />

FRANÇAFRIQUE<br />

Today this relationship is often<br />

referred to in France as la Françafrique. The<br />

term is not a new one, however, and its<br />

meaning has changed over time along with<br />

the shifting relationship between France and<br />

7 Guy Martin, “Francophone Africa in the Context of<br />

Franco-African Relations,” in Africa in World Politics,<br />

eds. John W. Haberson and Donald Rothchild<br />

(Boulder, CO: Westview 1995), 178.<br />

8 Xavier Renou, “A New French Policy For Africa?”<br />

Journal of Contemporary African Studies, 20, no. 1, (2002):<br />

10.<br />

9 Siradag, “Understanding French Foreign and<br />

Security Policy towards Africa”, 100.<br />

her former African colonies. It was in 1963<br />

that Felix Houphouët-Boigny, former<br />

president of Cote d’Ivoire, coined the term<br />

Françafrique. Initially Houphouët-Boigny’s<br />

notion of Françafrique was positive, and was<br />

used “to describe the common destiny and<br />

promote the special relationship between<br />

France and Africa that he supported and<br />

wanted to maintain.” 10 But today the term<br />

has negative connotations, often used to<br />

denounce France’s alleged neocolonial<br />

relationship with its former colonies.<br />

Andrew McKillop has described the notion<br />

of Françafrique as “a colonial hangover.” 11<br />

François Xavier Vershave, founder of the<br />

NGO Survie, used the term Françafrique to<br />

describe “the unsullied tip of the iceberg [of<br />

Franco-African relations]: France as the best<br />

friend of Africa, development and<br />

democracy.” 12 What lies beneath is a<br />

complicated connection that many believe<br />

signifies France’s enduring domination of its<br />

former colonies.<br />

In 2012, Hollande promised to<br />

move away from Françafrique behavior.<br />

During his first visit to the continent, in<br />

Senegal, Hollande declared, “The time of<br />

Françafrique is over: there is France, there is<br />

Africa, and there is the partnership between<br />

France and Africa, with relations based on<br />

respect, brightness, and solidarity.” 13 Yet<br />

just three months later, he sent French<br />

troops to Mali, after having expressed that<br />

he would not send French troops on the<br />

10 Tony Chafer, “Hollande and Africa Policy,” Modern<br />

Contemporary France, 22, no. 4 (2014): 529.<br />

11 Andrew McKillop, “What’s Really Behind France’s<br />

Sudden Scramble to Save Central Africa”, 21 st Century<br />

Wire, December 6, 2013, accessed on Nov. 30, 2014,<br />

http://21stcenturywire.com/2013/12/06/whatsreally-behind-frances-sudden-scramble-to-savecentral-africa/<br />

12 Francois X. Vershave, “Defining Francafrique”,<br />

Survie, February 18, 2006, accessed Nov. 27, 2014,<br />

http://survie.org/francafrique/article/definingfrancafrique-by-François<br />

13 “François Hollande à Dakar: ‘Le temps de la<br />

Françafrique est révolu,’” Le Monde, October 12,<br />

2012, accessed November 27, 2014,<br />

http://www.lemonde.fr/afrique/article/2012/10/12<br />

/hollande-exprime-sa-grande-confiance-dans-lesenegal-et-l-afrique_1774886_3212.html<br />

34 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 34


ground, 14 but would instead support an<br />

African-led force to deal with the crisis. The<br />

French intervention in Mali is highly<br />

complex in a number of ways, evident<br />

through the multitude of interpretations<br />

concerning French involvement in the<br />

conflict.<br />

UNDERSTANDING OPERATION<br />

SERVAL<br />

Operation Serval was a successful<br />

effort to push Islamic militants out of Mali.<br />

It was President Hollande’s first<br />

intervention in the region, spanning a total<br />

of 19 months, from January 2013 to July<br />

2014. On January 11, 2013, after new<br />

clashes between the army and insurgent<br />

groups, President Hollande announced the<br />

launching of a military operation: Serval.<br />

Just a day later, hundreds of French troops<br />

were involved in the military operation in<br />

Mali. The French army, navy, and air force<br />

were all deployed to assist in the operation.<br />

It was led by approximately 4,000 French<br />

troops supported by 2,000 Chadians and<br />

implemented in coordination with the<br />

Malian army. In fact, assistance from France<br />

was specifically requested from the Malian<br />

government. The operation was considered<br />

a success. Three of the five Islamic militant<br />

leaders were killed and the militant groups<br />

were driven from cities and later from the<br />

mountains of Adrar. 15<br />

President Hollande celebrated this<br />

triumph on a visit to the capital of Bamako<br />

where, clearly impressed by the strength of<br />

the popular welcome in the streets, he<br />

claimed, “I have just, without a doubt,<br />

experienced the most important day of my<br />

14 “François Hollande: ‘Je viens pour ecrire avec<br />

l’Afrique une nouvelle page,’” RFI, November 10,<br />

2012, accessed December 3, 2014,<br />

http://www.rfi.fr/afrique/20121011-Françoishollande-afrique-francophonie-sommet-interviewnouvelle-page/<br />

15 Isaline Bergamaschi, “French Military Intervention<br />

in Mali: Inevitable, Consensual, Yet Insufficient,”<br />

Stability: International Journal of Security and Development,<br />

2, no.2 (2013), accessed December 3, 2014.<br />

http://www.stabilityjournal.org/rt/printerFriendly/s<br />

ta.bb/70<br />

political life.” 16 The intervention received a<br />

huge amount of popular support from<br />

Malians, and France’s action “has very<br />

seldom been accused of neocolonialism<br />

internationally.” 17 This may be in part due<br />

to historical reasons and the fact that Mali<br />

doesn’t quite fall under the category of the<br />

French pré carré, a term used to describe<br />

France’s sphere of influence in Africa: the<br />

country assumed one of the more radical<br />

positions towards Paris, unilaterally<br />

declaring independence in 1960.<br />

This is why Tony Chafer, professor<br />

of French Area studies at Portsmouth<br />

University, argues, “the presentation of<br />

France’s military intervention in the country<br />

in 2013 as the latest avatar of the Françafrique<br />

tradition is at the very least misleading,<br />

insofar as it fails to take account of the<br />

complex, often tense nature of Franco-<br />

Malian relations in the post-colonial<br />

period.” 18 This refutes the notion of<br />

Françafrique as a model of analysis for the<br />

French intervention in Mali as it<br />

oversimplifies a long and complex history<br />

between France and Africa.<br />

The intervention in Mali also<br />

received praise, in part due to Hollande’s<br />

reluctance to intervene in Africa, a striking<br />

contrast to former president Nicolas<br />

Sarkozy. Sarkozy had a history of using<br />

aggressive foreign relation moves to gain or<br />

maintain popularity at home. In August<br />

2008, for example, he succeeded<br />

in negotiating a Russo-Georgian ceasefire<br />

without being invited to be a<br />

peacemaker. In 2011, Sarkozy took France<br />

to war in Libya without informing his<br />

parliament or foreign minister, Alain Juppé.<br />

In opposition, “the trouble taken by<br />

Hollande to seek African opinion before<br />

16 Ben Clift, and Raymond Kuhn, “The Hollande<br />

Presidency 2012-14,” Modern and Contemporary France,<br />

22, no. 4 (2014): 432.<br />

17 Isaline Bergamaschi and Mahamadou Diawara,<br />

“The French military intervention in Mali: Not<br />

exactly Françafrique but definitely postcolonial,” in<br />

Peace operations in the francophone world: global governance<br />

meets post-colonialism, ed. Bruno Charbonneau and<br />

Tony Chafer (Abingdon: Routledge, 2014), 137.<br />

18 Chafer, “Hollande and Africa Policy,” 516.<br />

35 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 35


going ahead with military intervention<br />

contrasted with past practice.” 19<br />

Yet, despite Hollande’s “subtler ear<br />

for the tone of African diplomacy,” 20 France<br />

still has a vested interest in the region, many<br />

aspects of which also contributed to<br />

France’s decision to intervene in Mali.<br />

Although France does not have specific<br />

economic interests in Mali, it certainly has<br />

economic interests in the wider region.<br />

Nigerian uranium, for instance, is central to<br />

France’s energy security: one quarter of<br />

France’s electricity production relies on<br />

uranium. There is also speculation<br />

concerning an interest in oil in the north of<br />

Mali that could be considered a new<br />

potential economic gain. However,<br />

Bergamaschi and Diawara assert, “the<br />

presence of oil resources has been suspected<br />

for a long time but never clearly and<br />

formally established.” 21<br />

French political motivations behind<br />

intervention should also be considered.<br />

France is a permanent member of the UN<br />

Security Council, and thus, has international<br />

obligations specifically to West Africa,<br />

where it has troops stationed in Senegal,<br />

Côte d’Ivoire, and Chad. As Chafer<br />

postulates, “faced with the threat of an<br />

Islamist takeover, the prospect of a<br />

humanitarian disaster and a request from the<br />

Malian government to intervene, it would<br />

have been extremely difficult for France to<br />

refuse.” 22 Chafer’s interpretation, that<br />

France is simply honoring its international<br />

obligations, may be overly generous. As<br />

Bergamaschi and Diawara explain, “acting<br />

for stability in Africa remains a key tool to<br />

defend the French seat at the UN Security<br />

Council.” 23 It should also be noted that<br />

African countries provide a valuable source<br />

of supportive votes for France at the UN.<br />

Although France may have simply been<br />

fulfilling its international duty, the benefits<br />

of intervention in this sense are undeniable.<br />

Even if circumstances forced France to<br />

intervene in Africa, to be present militarily<br />

in a number of African countries requires a<br />

type of Françafrique behavior.<br />

BARKHANE: CASTING FURTHER<br />

DOUBT<br />

In the summer of 2014, Hollande<br />

declared the objectives of Operation Serval<br />

accomplished, 24 but victory in Mali is not as<br />

absolute as has been suggested. This is<br />

demonstrated by the announcement in July<br />

2014 of a new military operation in the<br />

region: Operation Barkhane. Unlike Serval,<br />

Barkhane is preventative in its intent. While<br />

Serval aimed at fixing a problem that was<br />

deteriorating in Mali, Operation Barkhane<br />

has been labeled as a counterterrorist<br />

operation, although many specifics remain<br />

unclear. Hollande has said the Barkhane<br />

force will allow for a "rapid and efficient<br />

intervention in the event of a crisis” 25 in the<br />

region. This summer, Hollande began a<br />

three-nation visit to Africa, stopping in Côte<br />

d’Ivoire, Niger, and Chad. The focus of the<br />

visit was related to security, with Operation<br />

Serval coming to a close, only to be replaced<br />

by Operation Barkhane. Named after a<br />

crescent-shaped sand dune in the Saharan<br />

desert, the operation involves the<br />

deployment of 3,000 military personnel<br />

across the vast Sahel region, backed by six<br />

19 Paul Melly and Vincent Darracq, “A New Way to<br />

Engage? French Policy in Africa from Sarkozy to<br />

Hollande,” Chatham House Africa 2013, 10, accessed<br />

December 1, 2014.<br />

http://www.chathamhouse.org/sites/files/chathamh<br />

ouse/public/Research/Africa/0513pp_franceafrica.p<br />

df<br />

20 Ibid., 10.<br />

21 Bergamaschi and Diawara, “The French military<br />

intervention in Mali,” 141.<br />

22 Chafer, “Hollande and Africa Policy,” 524.<br />

23 Bergamaschi and Diawara, “The French military<br />

intervention in Mali”, 141.<br />

24 Sara M. Llana, “Mali, one year later: France's mission<br />

accomplished – but much left to do,” Christian Science<br />

Monitor, January 11, 2014, accessed December 1, 2014,<br />

http://www.csmonitor.com/World/Europe/2014/0<br />

111/Mali-one-year-later-France-s-missionaccomplished-but-much-left-to-do<br />

25 “Hollande announces new military operation in<br />

West Africa,” France<br />

24, July 19, 2014, accessed March 14, <strong>2015</strong>.<br />

http://www.france24.com/en/20140719-hollandeannounces-new-military-operation-west-africa/.<br />

36 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 36


fighter jets, 20 helicopters and three drones.<br />

The mission forms a belt of French military<br />

presence in five African countries: Burkina<br />

Faso, Mali, Chad, Niger and Mauritania.<br />

In an article published prior to the<br />

French president’s three-nation visit this<br />

summer, France 24 speculated, “mission<br />

accomplished or mission creep?” 26 Another<br />

article described Operation Barkhane as “a<br />

blurred French strategy.” 27 The notion of<br />

mission creep describes a gradual shift in<br />

objectives during the course of a military<br />

campaign, often resulting in an unplanned<br />

long-term commitment. Operation<br />

Barkhane can be interpreted as a form of<br />

“mission creep” in that it is the expansion of<br />

a project (Operation Serval), following initial<br />

successes. Mission creep is considered<br />

dangerous because it tends to forge a path<br />

of increasingly ambitious attempts at victory<br />

that ultimately result in great failure.<br />

Understood in these terms, the transition<br />

from Serval to Barkhane is inconsistent with<br />

Hollande’s promise to break from<br />

Françafrique, and Operation Barkhane may<br />

see French troops remain in the region for a<br />

number of years.<br />

Some have dubbed Mali as the next<br />

Afghanistan, 28 comparing Operation Barkhane<br />

to the U.S. “war on terror.” Using the same<br />

term coined at the dawn of U.S. involvement in<br />

Afghanistan, this labeling provokes many<br />

pejorative conceptions of the motivations<br />

behind the operation. If the notion of<br />

Françafrique is based on the exploitation of<br />

African countries for the advancement of<br />

France’s own power, viewing Operation<br />

26 Leela Jacinto, “It’s time for Africa again as<br />

Hollande starts three-nation visit”, France24, July 16,<br />

2014, accessed December 1, 2014,<br />

http://www.france24.com/en/20140716-francewest-africa-hollande-sahel-ivory-coast-niger-chad/.<br />

27 Sarah Diffalah, “DeServalàBarkhane:lamissionfrançaise<br />

loind'êtreterminée,” LeNouvelObservateur,July 16, 2014,<br />

accessed December 1, 2014,<br />

http://tempsreel.nouvelobs.com/guerre-aumali/20140715.OBS3744/mali-de-serval-a-barkhanela-mission-francaise-loin-d-etre-terminee.html.<br />

28 Mark Doyle, “Mali: Dangers of dealing with<br />

‘Afghanistan of West Africa,’” BBC News, June 14,<br />

2012, accessed December 5, 2014,<br />

http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-africa-18427541<br />

Barkhane in a similar light as the “war on<br />

terror” suggests that France is using the<br />

justificatory framework of counter-terrorism to<br />

remain involved in the region and benefit from<br />

this involvement. Such benefits include<br />

defending France’s position in the UN, as well<br />

as in the international arena.<br />

Hollande declared, during his<br />

presidential speech at Niemey, “Operation<br />

Barkhane is a structure built to accompany<br />

Africans and allow them to ensure their own<br />

security.” 29 The operation was presented as a<br />

way to regionalize counterterrorist movements,<br />

and to protect both the security of countries in<br />

the West and Central Africa, and that of<br />

France. Hollande has made sure to present<br />

Operation Barkhane under his initial promise<br />

to break away from Françafrique, just as he did<br />

with Operation Serval. There is one distinct<br />

difference, however. Operation Serval was<br />

launched after the interim Malian president<br />

Dioncounda Traoré asked for the assistance of<br />

the UN and of France. Operation Barkhane<br />

has no such precedent; it merely constitutes a<br />

continuation of the work of Operation Serval.<br />

Under Operation Serval, the French<br />

president and his advisors made claims to<br />

support Africans in their own development<br />

and security, when the role played by the<br />

French military was much more significant in<br />

reality. Hollande stated in late 2012, “France<br />

will not, in any case, intervene in Mali.” 30 Due<br />

to UN support, the mission was presented as<br />

multilateral. Once French troops arrived in<br />

Mali, France worked hard to ensure legality<br />

through the UN framework, making the case<br />

for an interpretation of UN Resolution 2085.<br />

This resolution, however, only authorized an<br />

29 Laurent Lagneau, “Selon M. Le Drian, l'objectif de<br />

l'opération Barkhane est “l'éradication du terrorisme<br />

jihadiste,”” Zone Militaire, July 22, 2014, accessed<br />

December 7, 2014,<br />

http://www.opex360.com/2014/07/22/selon-m-ledrian-lobjectif-de-loperation-barkhane-leradicationdu-terrorisme-jihadiste/.<br />

30 Ursula Soares, “Opération militaire au Mali : la<br />

France n’interviendra pas «elle-même»,” Radio France<br />

Internationale, November 13, 2012, accessed<br />

December 1, 2014,<br />

http://www.rfi.fr/afrique/20121113-operationmilitaire-mali-france-interviendra-pas-elle-memeunion-africaine-addis-abeba-conseil-securite/.<br />

37 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 37


African-led mission. 31 Bergamaschi and<br />

Diawara claim “France’s decision to<br />

intervene was unilateral,” 32 but more<br />

accurately, it was a bilateral decision,<br />

considering support was in fact requested by<br />

Mali. Had it not been, France may not have<br />

intervened. This is not to say France acted<br />

solely out of obligation or as a response to<br />

Mali’s cry for help, but rather that such a<br />

request provided an opportunity upon<br />

which France could capitalize.<br />

African responses to French<br />

intervention and involvement in the region<br />

are demonstrative of France’s special<br />

relationship with its former colonies.<br />

Despite the domination of the period of<br />

colonization, most countries achieved<br />

independence peacefully and responsibility<br />

rather than blame emerged in the discourse<br />

of the time.<br />

THE QUESTION OF DEBT<br />

The expectation that France can and<br />

should continue to help its former African<br />

colonies is inextricably linked to the notion<br />

of debt: France’s debt to Africa for the<br />

period of colonization as well as their debt<br />

for African military participation in several<br />

wars including the two world wars. Those<br />

African soldiers who served France are<br />

known as tirailleurs sénégalais (Senegalese<br />

infantrymen), despite recruitment not being<br />

limited to Senegal. It was during this time<br />

that Blaise Diagne, mayor of Dakar,<br />

“cultivated the expectation that those who<br />

served would be rewarded both symbolically<br />

and materially.” 33 This notion of “blood<br />

debt” (dette de sang) or colonial debt is still<br />

noticeably present today.<br />

Hollande was welcomed warmly in<br />

Cote d’Ivoire during his three-nation visit to<br />

31 United Nations, Resolution 2085, December 20,<br />

2012, accessed December 1, 2014,<br />

http://www.un.org/en/ga/search/view_doc.asp?sy<br />

mbol=S/RES/2085.<br />

32 Bergamaschi and Diawara, “The French military<br />

intervention in Mali: Not exactly Françafrique but<br />

definitely postcolonial,” 143.<br />

33 Gregory Mann, Native sons: West African veterans and<br />

France in the twentieth century, (Durham: Duke<br />

University Press, 2006), 70.<br />

Africa in July 2014. Fraternité Matin, the<br />

local Ivorian governmental news outlet, ran<br />

a piece on the day of the French president’s<br />

visit to Abidjan that stated, “Even if France<br />

does not, at this moment, provide support<br />

economically, she still has a lot to contribute<br />

for the reconstruction of our<br />

infrastructure.” 34 There is a tendency to<br />

think France is responsible for development<br />

in its former colonies: both from citizens of<br />

former French colonies, and from within<br />

the French government itself.<br />

This notion of debt may help to<br />

explain why the French intervention in Mali<br />

was received with such popular support in<br />

the country. During a speech delivered in<br />

Bamako in February 2013, the French<br />

president said, “I remember that when<br />

France was attacked, when she was looking<br />

for assistance and allies, when she was<br />

threatened, when her territorial unity was at<br />

stake, who came to support her then? Africa<br />

did, Mali did, thanks to Mali. Today we are<br />

paying our debt to Mali.” 35 Even the choice<br />

of the Chadian capital N’Djamena as the<br />

headquarters of Operation Barkhane could<br />

be interpreted as a reward for Chad’s timely<br />

intervention in Northern Mali. In early 2013<br />

Chad sent troops to support Operation<br />

Serval, providing essential support to France<br />

with their experience in desert warfare.<br />

During a speech delivered in front of the<br />

French community at N’Djamena<br />

announcing the launch of Operation<br />

Barkhane, Hollande thanked Chad a number<br />

of times, stating, “I wanted to express to<br />

you my gratitude.” 36 His presentation of this<br />

34 Venance Konan, “Akwaba, Hollande!”, Fraternité<br />

Matin, July 17, 2014, accessed December 2, 2014,<br />

http://www.fratmat.info/edito/item/17429-akwabahollande.<br />

35 François Hollande, cited in Bergamaschi and<br />

Diawara, “The French military intervention in Mali:<br />

Not exactly Françafrique but definitely postcolonial,”<br />

146.<br />

36 Francois Hollande, “Discours du président<br />

François Hollande devant la<br />

communauté française à Ndjamena,” Elysee, July 19,<br />

2014, accessed December 5, 2014,<br />

http://www.elysee.fr/assets/pdf/discours-dupresident-François-hollande-devant-la-communautefrancaise-a-ndjamena-2.pdf<br />

38 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 38


new operation within a context of<br />

appreciation demonstrates that a form of<br />

postcolonial debt still exists between France<br />

and its former colonies, and is being used as<br />

a way to justify involvement in the region.<br />

France’s notion of debt to its former<br />

colonies is a dangerous one. It perpetuates a<br />

postcolonial political community that makes<br />

it extremely hard for France to cut ties from<br />

her former African colonies. The notion of<br />

debt is problematic in two ways. First, it<br />

provides a justification for France to stay<br />

involved in African affairs. Second, it<br />

normalizes French involvement in Africa<br />

among the African population.<br />

The central role to be played by<br />

Chad in Operation Barkhane is also<br />

concerning, given that the President of<br />

Chad since 1996, Idriss Déby, is widely<br />

considered to be a dictator. 37 Déby‘s<br />

administration is widely believed to be<br />

responsible for the disappearance of the<br />

opposition leader, Ibni Oumar Mahamat<br />

Saleh. 38 Saleh disappeared after his arrest by<br />

the Chadian government in 2008.<br />

Previously, he served in the Chadian army<br />

and was made commander-in-chief under<br />

Hissène Habré. In 1985, he was removed<br />

from his post and sent to Paris to pursue a<br />

course at the École de Guerre.<br />

THE ROLE OF LEADERSHIP IN THE<br />

FRANCAFRIQUE RELATIONSHIP<br />

One fundamental aspect of<br />

Françafrique has been the close bond shared<br />

by French and African leaders. Many<br />

African leaders at some point attended<br />

university in Paris, or elsewhere in France,<br />

where they met their French counterparts.<br />

This was the case with many prominent<br />

37 Joshua Norman, “The world’s enduring dictators:<br />

Idriss Déby, Chad,” CBS News, June 19, 2011,<br />

accessed December 9, 2014,<br />

http://www.cbsnews.com/news/the-worldsenduring-dictators-idriss-Déby-chad-19-06-2011/<br />

38 “Chad: Repressive tactics against government<br />

critics must come to an end,” Amnesty International,<br />

October 24, 2013, accessed April 11, <strong>2015</strong>,<br />

https://www.amnesty.org/en/articles/news/2013/1<br />

0/chad-repressive-tactics-against-government-criticsmust-come-end/.<br />

figures, of which Leopold Sédar Senghor<br />

and Georges Pompidou are good examples.<br />

Senghor served as Senegal’s first president<br />

for over two decades, and Pompidou was<br />

Prime Minister of France and later President<br />

from 1969 until his death in 1974. Their<br />

friendship began in 1929-30 and Senghor<br />

once admitted in an interview that it was<br />

Pompidou “who converted me to<br />

socialism.” 39 It is interesting to note that<br />

Déby also has this academic connection<br />

with France, but what is even more<br />

concerning is the new relationship between<br />

Hollande and Déby.<br />

Recently, with the announcement of<br />

Operation Barkhane and the use of Chad as<br />

the headquarters of the mission, Hollande<br />

has established diplomatic relations with<br />

Déby. During his speech at N’Djamena on<br />

July 19, 2014, Hollande stated, “We have a<br />

deep seeded relationship of cooperation<br />

with Chad. And a solid and precious<br />

relationship with Déby.” 40 However, one<br />

reporter at the summit tweeted that<br />

Hollande in fact left at the start of Déby’s<br />

speech and only returned upon its close:<br />

“@fhollande has returned to the room to<br />

listen to Paul Biya after blowing off Déby’s<br />

speech @OIFfrancophonie #NAOIF14.” 41<br />

From this account, it seems that the<br />

relationship between the two leaders may<br />

not be as amicable as initially perceived.<br />

This does not, however, diminish the<br />

concern caused by collaborating with a<br />

dictator known to disregard human rights.<br />

It is, of course, far too easy to judge<br />

President Hollande for his actions, especially<br />

in the context of Françafrique, when the<br />

reality is that, “military interventions in Mali<br />

39 Leopold S. Senghor, cited in Jean-François Sirinelli,<br />

“Deux etudiants “coloniaux” à Paris à l’aube des<br />

anneés trente,” Vingtième Siècle, 18, (April – June<br />

1988): 81.<br />

40 Lénaïg Bredoux, “Hollande au Tchad: Comment<br />

Idriss Déby est redevenue le meilleur ami de la<br />

France,” Makaila, plume combattante et indépendante, July<br />

19, 2014, accessed December 3, 2014,<br />

http://www.mediapart.fr/journal/international/1907<br />

14/hollande-au-tchad-comment-idriss-Déby-estredevenu-le-meilleur-ami-de-la-france.<br />

41 Thierry Hot’s Twitter account, accessed December<br />

3, 2014, https://twitter.com/Hotthierry1<br />

39 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 39


and Central Afrique mean there is no way<br />

around the despot Idriss Déby.” 42 Chad<br />

holds a very important position<br />

geographically in the region. It is true,<br />

however, that upon his election, Hollande<br />

not only promised at break from the old<br />

days of Françafrique, but also went so far as<br />

to condemn Déby. That has all changed<br />

now, in the name of security, and Chad is<br />

presented as vital, militarily (as proven<br />

during Operation Serval) and geographically,<br />

to the success of Operation Barkhane.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

It certainly is problematic to<br />

substantiate claims that Hollande’s actions<br />

comprise a definite return to Françafrique. As<br />

Chafer’s argument highlights, the use of<br />

Françafrique as a tool of analysis<br />

oversimplifies a very complex relationship.<br />

The fact that a relationship exists at all<br />

cannot be construed as Françafrique<br />

behavior, given France’s complicated history<br />

with Africa as well as their economic ties to<br />

the continent. It should be recognized that<br />

France’s role in Africa will always be shaped<br />

by history, by economics, and by<br />

international pressures. France has a very<br />

unique historical position concerning Africa,<br />

and this aspect of the relationship will not<br />

change: it is a factor that will always shape<br />

France’s policy toward Africa. Yet close<br />

historical bonds do not necessarily indicate a<br />

future of Françafrique, just as the very<br />

existence of a close relationship doesn’t<br />

immediately indicate a return to Françafrique.<br />

The root of the problem may be that<br />

Hollande’s promise to break with<br />

Françafrique was simply too ambitious, and<br />

unrealistic. The mistake the president has<br />

made is not in simply maintaining a<br />

relationship with former colonies, or even<br />

supporting them (this may very well always<br />

be the case due to deep historical roots), but<br />

with trying to utterly deny the power of<br />

such a deep-seeded bond as he did back in<br />

2012. Hollande’s presidency has proven that<br />

42 Bredoux, “Hollande au Tchad.”<br />

completely avoiding Africa is not a viable<br />

option for France. As Mustapha Tossa,<br />

editor-in-chief of Monte Carlo Doualiya,<br />

France 24’s Arabic language sister radio<br />

station, explains, “The fact is, France was<br />

forced to intervene in Africa, to be present<br />

militarily in a number of African countries,<br />

which requires a type<br />

of Françafrique behavior. So, Françafrique is<br />

still alive under François Hollande. And I<br />

do not see how he can get rid of it since<br />

France is so engulfed in protecting its allies<br />

and interests in the region.” 43 It is for this<br />

reason that no matter how lightly President<br />

Hollande treads in Africa; he will always fall<br />

under criticism concerning the Françafrique<br />

nature of his policies, as will presidents to<br />

come.<br />

While it is right to be skeptical of<br />

President Hollande’s motivations behind<br />

Operation Serval and Operation Barkhane,<br />

it is most certainly true that thus far, he has<br />

proceeded with more caution toward Africa<br />

than any other president before him.<br />

Hollande’s desire to lead France away from<br />

Françafrique may be genuine, but reality and<br />

circumstance will not permit him to fully<br />

follow through on his promise.<br />

CARMEN CUESTA<br />

ROCA is a Masters<br />

student in Journalism<br />

and French Studies at<br />

NYU. An avid learner of<br />

new cultures and<br />

languages, she hails<br />

from the UK, but has<br />

Spanish heritage.<br />

Carmen is working<br />

toward a career in<br />

journalism - currently a<br />

local news junkie - but she hopes to spend<br />

her post-NYU days reporting<br />

internationally. This summer she will travel<br />

to Haiti to report for her thesis and on other<br />

stories.<br />

43 Mustapha Tossa, quoted in Jacinto, “It’s time for<br />

Africa again as Hollande starts three-nation visit.”<br />

40 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 40


China’s Economic<br />

Espionage<br />

Stealing, Not Destroying<br />

Reema Hibrawi<br />

This paper seeks to examine the<br />

economic espionage threat to the<br />

national security of the United States<br />

from the Chinese government in the private<br />

and public sector. In this paper, economic<br />

espionage will refer to the unauthorized<br />

access and use of information by a foreign<br />

entity for strategic, tactical, or economic<br />

purposes. 1 The theft of trade secrets with the<br />

intent of an economic benefit by a foreign<br />

power, also falls under economic espionage. 2<br />

The key research questions of this paper are:<br />

1) Which U.S. targets are pursued by the<br />

Chinese government? 2) Why is China<br />

engaging in economic espionage against the<br />

U.S.? 3) What are the implications for U.S.<br />

national security?<br />

This paper seeks to specifically discuss<br />

the economic, military, and security risks to<br />

U.S. national security. Economic risks include<br />

the loss of trade secrets and competitive<br />

advantage. Military risks include the theft of<br />

strategic information on operations,<br />

equipment, and personnel. 3 Security risks refer<br />

1 Economic Espionage Act of 1996: Title 18 Crimes and<br />

Criminal Procedure, Part I Crimes, Chapter 90<br />

Protection of Trade Secrets, Pub. L. No. 104-294, 110<br />

Stat. 3488 (Oct. 11, 1996), codified at 18 U.S.C. §1831.<br />

Passed as part of the National Information Infrastructure<br />

Protection Act of 1996.<br />

2 Charles Doyle, “Stealing Trade Secrets and Economic<br />

Espionage: An Overview of 18 U.S.C. 1831 and 1832,”<br />

Congressional Research Service (July 25, 2014).<br />

3 Testimony of Larry M. Wortzel, “Cyber Espionage<br />

and the Theft of US Intellectual Property and<br />

Technology,” before the House of Representatives,<br />

to infrastructure and government functions<br />

that rely on digital networks. The main focus<br />

will be on Chinese government network<br />

exploitation and attacks, as well as intellectual<br />

property theft. 4<br />

The analysis predicts that the Chinese<br />

government will continue to focus on<br />

persistent and aggressive economic espionage<br />

of the United States. This judgment is made<br />

due to the vast information from private<br />

security consulting and public intelligence<br />

agencies on attacks originating from China,<br />

and the current Chinese cyber strategy. It is<br />

less clear how the Chinese will continue to use<br />

economic espionage as a tool to maintain their<br />

economic growth. This uncertainty is due to<br />

the opaque and complex internal strategy on<br />

China’s economic espionage. This may or may<br />

not be the main tool or focus for China’s<br />

economic growth moving forward. Just as<br />

uncertain but highly probable is that the<br />

Chinese will continue to resist ratifying an<br />

international legal framework for cyber<br />

monitoring and security that is restrictive.<br />

This is based on failed negotiations in the<br />

past, and China’s continued focus on<br />

maintaining legitimacy through its domestic<br />

and foreign policies.<br />

RATIONALE<br />

Historically, China is not known for<br />

its prowess in modernity. It has lagged behind<br />

the U.S. in innovation and resources in much<br />

of the 20 th Century. China was inefficient,<br />

stagnant, and poor due to tight economic<br />

control and isolation by the state. 5 A shift<br />

occurred in the late 1970’s, with the<br />

Committee on Energy and Commerce Subcommittee<br />

on Oversight and Investigations (July 9, 2013).<br />

4 Mark Lowenthal, Intelligence: From Secrets to Policy, 6 th<br />

Edition (Sage/CQ Press, 2014), 456.<br />

5 Wayne Morrison, “China’s Economic Rise: History,<br />

Trends, Challenges, and Implications for the United<br />

States,” Congressional Research Service (October 9, 2014).<br />

41 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 41


implementation of free market reforms 6 China<br />

continued to push for foreign direct<br />

investment (FDI) to this economic<br />

development. 7 It has become more influential<br />

as a result of improving its technology and<br />

intelligence capabilities. 8 This includes the<br />

modernization of its signal intelligence<br />

(SIGINT). 9 It has also shown space-borne<br />

capabilities in the form of anti-satellite<br />

(ASAT) tests in 2007 and 2013. 10 In the<br />

education sector, the state has emphasized<br />

science fields to continue this growth. There<br />

has since been an increase in Chinese students<br />

attending physics and computer science<br />

programs in U.S. universities and graduate<br />

programs. 11 This is seen as both an effort to<br />

modernize the population and develop cyber<br />

hacking capabilities for state use. The aim of<br />

modernizing into an information and<br />

industrial society has inspired the<br />

Informatization Plan of 2006. 12 One of the<br />

main goals is to close the digital divide. 13<br />

China is on track to do just that as illustrated<br />

by its successful economic espionage on U.S.<br />

civilian and military organizations. 14 With its<br />

growing power as a world economy and<br />

6 Beina Xu and Eleanor Albert, “The Chinese<br />

Communist Party: Backgrounders,” Council on Foreign<br />

Relations (November 17, 2014).<br />

7 Jim Lewis, “China Economic Reform Timeline: Jim<br />

Lewis Blog,” Center for Strategic & International Studies<br />

(December 11, 2014).<br />

8 Wayne Morrison, “China’s Economic Rise: History,<br />

Trends, Challenges, and Implications for the United<br />

States,” Congressional Research Service (October 9, 2014).<br />

9 Mark Lowenthal, Intelligence: From Secrets to Policy, 456.<br />

10 Ibid.<br />

11 Ibid.<br />

12 Amy Chang, “Warring State: China’s Cybersecurity<br />

Strategy,” Center for New American Security (December<br />

2014).<br />

13 Zhongzhou Li, “China’s Information Strategy and its<br />

Impact on Trade in ICT Goods and ICT Services,”<br />

UNCTAD Expert Meeting, in Support of the<br />

Implementation and Follow-Up of WSIS: Using ICTs<br />

to Achieve Growth and Development (December<br />

2006).<br />

14 Ibid.<br />

increasing need for resources, Chinese<br />

intelligence and technology capabilities have<br />

improved to meet these demands.<br />

IMPORTANCE TO THE U.S.<br />

Along with these developments, the<br />

cyber domain is relatively new and<br />

unregulated, which makes economic<br />

espionage without consequences more<br />

prevalent. There are no legal frameworks to<br />

monitor cyber security at the international<br />

level, 15 and no precedent exists in policy at the<br />

domestic or international level. 16 The<br />

sovereignty of digital information is a point of<br />

contention between states like China and the<br />

U.S.; China prefers a more flexible<br />

interpretation which will not affect its<br />

domestic and political stability. 17 This has led<br />

to stalled agreements on international cyber<br />

security and norms. 18 The U.S. infrastructure<br />

is reliant on digital networks for its electricity,<br />

water, transportation, flight travel, and the<br />

economy. 19 Like most industrialized states, the<br />

U.S. is more vulnerable to economic<br />

espionage due to the level of integration<br />

between digital networks and national<br />

infrastructure. 20 Government social services<br />

like healthcare, industry, and commerce have<br />

transferred to digital structures. Besides the<br />

government, the public also is increasing its<br />

use and trust of digital technologies. 21 One<br />

third of the world is digitally connected and<br />

15 James Clapper, Worldwide Threat Assessment of the US<br />

Intelligence Community (January 29, 2014).<br />

16 Michael Hayden, “The Future of Things ‘Cyber’,”<br />

Strategic Studies Quarterly (<strong>Spring</strong> 2011).<br />

17 Amy Chang, “Warring State: China’s Cybersecurity<br />

Strategy,” Center for New American Security (December<br />

2014).<br />

18 Ibid.<br />

19 White House Online, “International Strategy for<br />

Cyberspace” (May 2011).<br />

20 James Clapper. Worldwide Threat Assessment of the US<br />

Intelligence Community (January 29, 2014).<br />

21 Ibid.<br />

42 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 42


this is likely to increase as more countries<br />

modernize and develop technology. 22<br />

For these reasons, the Director of<br />

National Intelligence (DNI) threat assessment<br />

of 2013 lists cyber security as a current and<br />

growing future threat to the U.S. and<br />

highlights China and Russia as the most<br />

pervasive and persistent in attacks against the<br />

U.S. 23 Chinese programs infiltrated over 1,295<br />

computers in 103 nations. 24 They target U.S.<br />

national defense and national lab sites, 25 as<br />

well as cyber and technology firms. 26 These<br />

are substantial motivations for cyber security<br />

and protection from economic espionage as a<br />

key strategic initiative for the most recent<br />

Department of Defense (DoD) strategy of<br />

2011. 27 The executive branch also lists<br />

cybercrime as a key focus in the White House<br />

International Strategy for Cyberspace. 28<br />

ANALYSIS<br />

China has persistently denied<br />

existence of cyber units or economic<br />

espionage. It describes these claims as<br />

fictitious and baseless. 29 In 2010, of 614<br />

known advanced persistent threats (APT)<br />

with distinct IP addresses attacking<br />

infrastructure systems, 100% were found<br />

22 Ibid.<br />

23 Ibid.<br />

24 A study undertaken by the University of Toronto in<br />

2009, in Mark Lowenthal, Intelligence: From Secrets to<br />

Policy, 457.<br />

25 Mark Lowenthal, Intelligence: From Secrets to Policy, 457.<br />

26 Mandiant Online. “APT1: Exposing One of China’s<br />

Cyber Espionage Units.” A private security consulting<br />

service periodically releases cyber threat reports against<br />

the US and private sector companies.<br />

27 Department of Defense, “Department of Defense<br />

Strategy for Operations in Cyberspace” (July 2011).<br />

28 White House Online, “International Strategy for<br />

Cyberspace” (May 2011).<br />

29 Adam Segal, “Axiom and the Deepening Divide in<br />

U.S – China Cyber Relations,” Council on Foreign<br />

Relations (October 29, 2014).<br />

operating out of Shanghai. 30 A prominent<br />

espionage unit, referred to as APT1, has<br />

instigated massive attacks and continues to<br />

steal huge quantities of information.<br />

Hundreds of investigations on economic<br />

espionage found that most activities<br />

originated in China and with government<br />

knowledge. 31 The extent of the attacks and<br />

resilience of the group suggest they have<br />

strong financial backing in addition to a<br />

sophisticated structure. With the highly<br />

monitored Chinese environment, it is unlikely<br />

the state is unaware. Evidence suggests the<br />

state must be supporting these activities<br />

because its attacks have not stopped. 32 The<br />

top industries include information technology,<br />

high-tech electronics, aerospace, public<br />

administration, and satellites and<br />

telecommunications. 33 Strong evidence shows<br />

that APT1 is Unit 61398 which is the People’s<br />

Liberation Army (PLA) Third Department<br />

cyber espionage unit. Cyber activity originates<br />

in the same area where Unit 61398 is<br />

located. 34 The same structure, mission, and<br />

methodology exists in both units. The<br />

similarities between the two groups are<br />

difficult to ignore. The sophistication and<br />

investment in this espionage unit explains the<br />

assessment of China continuing persistent<br />

economic espionage against the U.S. as likely.<br />

The U.S. must continue to prepare for China’s<br />

espionage activities.<br />

Of exemplary importance, Unit 61398<br />

targets civilian technology and proprietary<br />

information. Evidence shows that APT1<br />

started stealing data as early as 2006. 35<br />

Information that is targeted includes strategic<br />

plans, goals, calendar items, optimization<br />

30 Mandiant Online. “APT1: Exposing One of China’s<br />

Cyber Espionage Units,” 2013.<br />

31 Ibid.<br />

32 Ibid.<br />

33 Ibid.<br />

34 Ibid.<br />

35 Mandiant Online. “Trends: Beyond the Breach, 2014<br />

Threat Report.”<br />

43 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 43


processes, and joint venture information. 36<br />

This suggests that the attacks are meant to<br />

understand how executives and decision<br />

makers think. 37 China is looking to gain<br />

influence through several means: economic,<br />

political, diplomatic, and military platforms.<br />

China-based attacks steal ideas and the<br />

process to developing those ideas. The cost<br />

for these activities is minimal. Risk is low and<br />

gaining access to large quantities of<br />

information can be done quickly by<br />

manipulating networks, e-mail, and digital<br />

downloads to external storage devices. 38<br />

Detection is difficult over networks because<br />

the location of the perpetrator can also be<br />

masked. 39<br />

U.S. private sector firms, academia,<br />

and private citizens of various countries are<br />

prime targets for China. Evidence shows that<br />

Marathon Oil, ExxonMobil, and<br />

ConocoPhillips were hacked in the summer of<br />

2008 and lost data detailing the quantity,<br />

value, and location of oil discoveries around<br />

the world. The loss of such data per company<br />

ranges in the millions of dollars. 40 The<br />

Chinese are the most pervasive and relentless<br />

actors in economic espionage, besides<br />

Russia. 41 The U.S. is the leader in<br />

technological and economic development<br />

which makes it a target by its competitors, and<br />

especially China. 42 Information and stolen<br />

data is provided to Chinese state owned<br />

enterprises which cuts costs, research and<br />

development timelines, and improves the<br />

competitive edge of these industries. 43 The<br />

economy as a whole can also be damaged by<br />

the compromise of private sector trade<br />

secrets, which can affect job creation, profits,<br />

and future innovation. 44<br />

Military economic espionage has<br />

targeted several DoD weapons systems<br />

including ballistic-missile defense systems,<br />

Black Hawk helicopters, and combat ships. 45<br />

Military operations and the individuals<br />

involved are compromised when military<br />

documents are stolen. China seeks<br />

information on the manufacture of weapons<br />

and their systems to replicate and counter<br />

their designs. This is an effort to modernize<br />

the state and improve its military capabilities.<br />

Evidence of this is seen through its antisatellite<br />

tests to counter U.S. military use of<br />

satellites for offensive behavior. 46 More<br />

specifically, evidence has also shown that<br />

Chinese hackers stole classified information in<br />

February 2012 about the technology behind<br />

the F-35 joint strike fighters. 47<br />

CHINESE STRATEGY<br />

Currently, China’s cyber strategy is an<br />

extension of its national security strategy. This<br />

36 Ibid.<br />

37 Ibid.<br />

38 “Foreign Spies Stealing US Economic Secrets in<br />

Cyberspace,” Counterintelligence Security, Office of<br />

the National Counterintelligence Executive, Report to<br />

Congress on Foreign Economic Collection and Industrial<br />

Espionage, 2009-2011 (October 2011).<br />

39 Ibid.<br />

40 “Cybersecurity: A list of significant cyber events<br />

since 2006,” Center for Strategic and International<br />

Studies (April <strong>2015</strong>).<br />

41 “Foreign Spies Stealing US Economic Secrets in<br />

Cyberspace,” Counterintelligence Security, Office of<br />

the National Counterintelligence Executive, Report to<br />

Congress on Foreign Economic Collection and Industrial<br />

Espionage, 2009-2011 (October 2011).<br />

42 Ibid.<br />

43 Testimony of Larry M. Wortzel, “Cyber Espionage<br />

and the Theft of US Intellectual Property and<br />

Technology,” before the House of Representatives,<br />

Committee on Energy and Commerce Subcommittee<br />

on Oversight and Investigations (July 9, 2013).<br />

44 “Foreign Spies Stealing US Economic Secrets in<br />

Cyberspace,” Counterintelligence Security, Office of<br />

the National Counterintelligence Executive, Report to<br />

Congress on Foreign Economic Collection and Industrial<br />

Espionage, 2009-2011 (October 2011).<br />

45 Ibid.<br />

46 Mark Lowenthal. Intelligence: From Secrets to Policy, 457.<br />

47 “Cybersecurity: A List of Significant Cyber Events<br />

Since 2006,” Center for Strategic and International<br />

Studies (April <strong>2015</strong>).<br />

44 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 44


is to maintain legitimacy of the Chinese<br />

Communist Party (CCP). It is likely China will<br />

resist ratifying an international legal<br />

framework to maintain legitimacy. The CCP<br />

maintains legitimacy by ensuring domestic<br />

stability, military modernization, economic<br />

growth, and territorial integrity. 48<br />

In order to become a better innovator<br />

of information and industry, Chinese<br />

domestic policy needs to focus on technology<br />

and science and the current leader in both<br />

technology and innovation is the U.S. It<br />

follows that China’s main targets are U.S.<br />

private companies, military, and government.<br />

Chinese economic espionage serves several<br />

purposes: political, military, and economic. 49<br />

China is simultaneously maintaining<br />

legitimacy, anticipating cyber conflict, and<br />

growing its economy. For these reasons, it is<br />

likely that China would use economic<br />

espionage as an integral tool for economic<br />

growth and other domestic policy objectives.<br />

Understanding that China seeks economic<br />

espionage for several reasons, mostly to<br />

maintain power and economic growth, is<br />

important in anticipating future U.S. targets.<br />

It has been argued that China is using<br />

economic espionage solely for military<br />

offensive strategy or economic growth. Either<br />

premise is too simplistic and overlooks the<br />

Chinese style of governance in the last<br />

century. As previously mentioned, a major<br />

objective of the CCP is to maintain its<br />

legitimacy. All policies, both domestic and<br />

foreign, are shaped by this priority of self-<br />

48 “Foreign Spies Stealing US Economic Secrets in<br />

Cyberspace,” Counterintelligence Security, Office of<br />

the National Counterintelligence Executive, Report to<br />

Congress on Foreign Economic Collection and Industrial<br />

Espionage, 2009-2011 (October 2011).<br />

49 James Lewis and Simon Hansen, “China’s<br />

cyberpower: International and Domestic Priorities,”<br />

Australian Strategic Policy Institute (November 12, 2014).<br />

preservation. 50 Because a major objective of<br />

the CCP is to maintain its political legitimacy,<br />

it is prone to using economic espionage to<br />

meet both objectives—military prowess and<br />

economic development, as both are important<br />

contributors to CCP’s legitimacy. The<br />

combination of military and economic growth<br />

is a stronger method of maintaining authority<br />

than either alone. The CCP has been in power<br />

for over eighty years, and has remained in<br />

power by maintaining political and economic<br />

stability. 51 Chinese President Xi Jingping has<br />

also emphasized the importance of cyber<br />

technology in China’s pursuit of power<br />

through the 2006 Informatization Plan, and in<br />

recent national security law drafted specifically<br />

to establish “systems of cyber and<br />

information security and national cyber<br />

sovereignty.” 52 This law highlights the<br />

importance of cyber technology and security<br />

for Xi and the CCP in maintaining legitimacy.<br />

Economic espionage is likely to continue to<br />

be a tool for that end.<br />

The U.S. does not have complete<br />

information about the motivations and<br />

patterns of Chinese economic espionage. This<br />

is because not every Chinese economic<br />

espionage attack has been successful or<br />

detected. 53 The limitations of the CCP cyber<br />

strategy is also unknown. Few public<br />

50 Amy Chang, “Warring State: China’s Cybersecurity<br />

Strategy,” Center for New American Security (December,<br />

2014).<br />

51 Beina Xu; Eleanor Albert, “The Chinese Communist<br />

Party: Backgrounders,” Council on Foreign Relations<br />

(November 17, 2014) ; Amy Chang, “Warring State:<br />

China’s Cybersecurity Strategy,” Center for New American<br />

Security (December 2014).<br />

52 “China defines overall national security outlook in<br />

draft law,” People’s Daily (April 20, <strong>2015</strong>).<br />

53 Testimony of Dr. Larry M. Wortzel before the<br />

House Armed Services Committee, “China’s Military<br />

Modernization and Cyber Activities,” Strategic Studies<br />

Quarterly 8, no. 1: 3-22. International Security and Counter<br />

Terrorism Reference Center (<strong>Spring</strong> 2014).<br />

45 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 45


documents exist on this secretive program. 54<br />

There are assumptions that the CCP would<br />

not steal information that could be seen as an<br />

act of war. Yet there is no evidence from the<br />

CCP or Xi if this assumption is accurate. The<br />

CCP may have its own unspoken rules about<br />

what to collect and what not to prioritize.<br />

This standard may be an understanding within<br />

the top leadership culture, not documented<br />

officially, and also kept secret.<br />

The highest priority for the Chinese<br />

government is maintaining domestic stability.<br />

If this were to change, China would be forced<br />

to focus on domestic rather than foreign<br />

policy. It is not likely that espionage acts<br />

would stop, but the attacks would decrease as<br />

focus is shifted to the domestic sphere and<br />

managing censorship or internal attacks. If<br />

China agrees to ratify an international legal<br />

framework, this might also alter the structure<br />

of China’s economic espionage units. China<br />

still believes it needs the information provided<br />

by its economic espionage units to modernize<br />

and grow, so again economic espionage would<br />

continue.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

The aim of Chinese espionage has<br />

historically been to gain an economic edge<br />

over its competitors. Because espionage has<br />

been a relatively low-cost method to obtain<br />

important technology for economic<br />

development, and because China needs these<br />

technologies at its current level of<br />

development, it is likely that such economic<br />

espionage will continue. On the other hand,<br />

this paper has found that China has not used<br />

its stolen information for military aggression,<br />

although it targets military intelligence in both<br />

nuclear and satellite classified information. 55 It<br />

is unlikely China will have a major cyber-<br />

54 Amy Chang, “Warring State: China’s Cybersecurity<br />

Strategy,” Center for New American Security (December,<br />

2014).<br />

55 Ibid.<br />

attack on U.S. infrastructure that would cause<br />

wide scale disruption. 56 It is also unlikely<br />

China will use cyber warfare in the next three<br />

years unless it believes its vital interest, the<br />

political legitimacy of the CCP regime, is<br />

violated.<br />

FURTHER READINGS:<br />

Chang, Amy. “Warring State: China’s<br />

Cybersecurity Strategy.” Center for New<br />

American Security. December, 2014.<br />

“Cybersecurity: A List of Significant Cyber Events<br />

Since 2006.” Center for Strategic and<br />

International Studies, April <strong>2015</strong>.<br />

Mandiant Online. “APT1: Exposing One of<br />

China’s Cyber Espionage<br />

Units.” https://www.mandiant.com/resource<br />

s/mandiant-reports/.<br />

Segal, Adam. “Axiom and the Deepening Divide<br />

in the U.S – China Cyber Relations.” Council<br />

on Foreign Relations: Net Politics. October 29,<br />

2014.<br />

White House Online. “International Strategy for<br />

Cyberspace.” May 2011.<br />

http://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/fil<br />

es/rss_viewer/international_strategy_for_cyb<br />

erspace.pdf.<br />

Wong, Edward. “For China, Cybersecurity is Part<br />

of Strategy for Protecting the Communist<br />

Party.” The New York Times. December, 3,<br />

2014.<br />

56 Adam Segal, “The code not taken: China, the United<br />

States, and the future of cyber espionage,” Bulletin of the<br />

Atomic Scientists (2013).<br />

46 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 46


Reema Hibrawi is a Syrian-American with an<br />

international background having lived and<br />

studied in the Middle East, Europe, and the US.<br />

Her educational background includes a<br />

Bachelor's of Science in Business<br />

Administration with a focus in HR, and<br />

currently is pursuing a Master's of Arts in<br />

International Relations at New York University.<br />

Currently a corporate planning intern at the<br />

Council on Foreign Relations (CFR) her career<br />

goals include continuing to work on<br />

international affairs and project management<br />

within civil society and international<br />

organizations, or think tanks with a<br />

concentration on post-conflict development,<br />

and diplomacy and civil society.<br />

47 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 47


The Anti-Communist<br />

Myth<br />

A critical examination of<br />

aggregate U.S. foreign policy<br />

analysis of the Cold War<br />

Dylan Heyden<br />

With the exception of being<br />

located on the same continent,<br />

there are perhaps no two South<br />

American countries that are more different<br />

than Argentina and Bolivia. Still, in light of<br />

their differences it is quite common for<br />

scholars to lump the two together along<br />

with other South and Central American<br />

countries when analyzing U.S. foreign<br />

policy pertaining to Latin America. This<br />

tendency is most evident in scholarly<br />

analysis of the Cold War era that often<br />

frames U.S. foreign policy decisions as<br />

being exclusively anti-communist.<br />

This paper examines U.S. foreign<br />

policy toward Argentina and Bolivia during<br />

the presidential administration of Richard<br />

Nixon. It postulates that the U.S. support<br />

of a coup in Bolivia and lack thereof in<br />

Argentina indicate the administration’s<br />

nuanced approach in foreign policymaking.<br />

It also argues that anti-communism was<br />

only one of a variety of factors to influence<br />

U.S. interventions in the region. This<br />

analysis seeks to expand current views on<br />

the transitory nature of Richard Nixon’s<br />

presidency vis-à-vis the Cold War, and the<br />

calculative and meticulous nature of the<br />

Richard Nixon-Henry Kissinger foreign<br />

policy-making mechanism. To do so, the<br />

first section will provide background<br />

information about the issue at hand—<br />

aggregated analysis that paints U.S. policy<br />

in Latin America with a broad brush. The<br />

second section will explain the historical<br />

context of the U.S.-backed coup in Bolivia,<br />

and its precursors. The third section will<br />

highlight the parallel sociopolitical situation<br />

in Argentina and identify a few similarities.<br />

The concluding section demonstrates that<br />

because the purely anti-communist thesis<br />

breaks down in the comparison of just two<br />

case studies, nuanced analysis that focuses<br />

on individual countries is more apt to<br />

explain the variety of factors guiding U.S.<br />

foreign policy decisions during the Cold<br />

War era.<br />

BACKGROUND<br />

Argentina and Bolivia occupy the<br />

same continent, share an official<br />

language—Spanish—but have little else in<br />

common. The first, a particularly large<br />

country with a culture of tango, mate, and<br />

strong European roots, takes pride in its<br />

heritage of gauchos de La Pampa<br />

(romanticized “cowboys”), asados<br />

(barbecues), and contributions to Latin<br />

American literature. Argentina has an<br />

immense coastline, but its crown jewel is its<br />

vibrant capital city, Buenos Aires, which is<br />

often referred to as the Paris of South<br />

America. Bolivia, on the other hand, is<br />

landlocked (and has been since the 19 th<br />

century). This is in some ways analogous to<br />

its current geopolitical predicament—being<br />

backed into a corner by three major South<br />

American players: Chile, Argentina, and<br />

Brazil. Bolivia is also smaller both in area<br />

and population than most of its neighbors<br />

(inhabitants number 10.5 million whereas<br />

the Buenos Aires metro area alone boasts<br />

15 million). 1 The ethnic makeup of Bolivia,<br />

1 Central Intelligence Agency, “South America:<br />

Bolivia,” The World Factbook.<br />

https://www.cia.gov/llibrary/publications/theworld-factbook/geos/bl.html;<br />

Central Intelligence<br />

48 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 48


which is mostly indigenous, is also of stark<br />

contrast to the country’s paler Argentinian<br />

counterparts, and the people’s habit of<br />

choice is chewing coca leaves or steeping<br />

them in a tea as opposed to drinking mate.<br />

In spite of these differences, it is<br />

quite common for scholars to focus their<br />

analysis of the impacts of U.S. foreign<br />

policy on the region—grouping the two<br />

countries together along with other South<br />

American nations and even Mexico, the<br />

Caribbean, and Central America. This is<br />

especially true in the context of the Cold<br />

War. For instance, Peter H. Smith says of<br />

the period that:<br />

The United States sought to<br />

extend and consolidate its<br />

political supremacy<br />

throughout the hemisphere.<br />

Launching an anticommunist<br />

crusade, the United States<br />

institutionalized military and<br />

political alliances with the<br />

nations of the region [and]<br />

offered to collaborate with<br />

authoritarian regimes so long<br />

as they were anticommunist. 2<br />

He argues, “By the mid 1950s,<br />

Washington laid down policy lines that<br />

would continue through the 1980s.” 3<br />

Spanning nearly 44 years (1947-1991), any<br />

claims about “Latin American” history, or<br />

U.S. foreign policy with respect to the<br />

region during this time deserve a great deal<br />

more nuance. While the Cold War was a<br />

period often characterized by monolithic<br />

anti-communist foreign policy, U.S. foreign<br />

policy towards Latin America was much<br />

Agency “Country Comparison: GDP - per Capita<br />

(PPP),” The World Factbook.<br />

2 Peter H. Smith, Talons of the Eagle: Dynamics of U.S.-<br />

Latin American Relations (New York: Oxford UP,<br />

1996), 117.<br />

3 Ibid.<br />

more fluid, and varied from country to<br />

country. The goal of the United States for<br />

Latin America as early as the mid-1950s, as<br />

Smith identifies, was to mitigate the<br />

“communist threat”. 4 The strategies of<br />

doing so, however, and the value ascribed<br />

to this policy depended as much on the<br />

global and regional context as on the<br />

person sitting in the oval office. Even a<br />

blanket statement like the “threat of<br />

communism” does not take into<br />

consideration the continuum of populist<br />

and leftist movements that had to be<br />

evaluated by U.S. foreign policy makers for<br />

their viability as threats to the United<br />

States. Moreover, different U.S. officials<br />

would likely describe what constitutes a<br />

threat differently.<br />

Shrouded in mystery, due in part to<br />

the social peculiarities of both figures, the<br />

Nixon-Kissinger relationship with respect<br />

to U.S. foreign policy is often represented<br />

as quintessentially Cold War. Early in his<br />

presidency, Nixon was an anti-communist<br />

ideologue with the primary objective of<br />

stopping the spread of communism. 5<br />

Kissinger, however, was very much a<br />

product of the realist school of thought in<br />

international relations and viewed power<br />

and its maintenance and protection as<br />

being at the core of the pursuit of U.S.<br />

interests. It was ultimately Kissinger’s<br />

realist approach in the calculation of<br />

foreign policy that came to heavily<br />

influence Nixon. 6 The vision of the duo as<br />

manipulative architects, bending<br />

international actors to their will for the<br />

sake of an anti-communist crusade,<br />

4 Ibid.<br />

5 Larry Ceplair, Anti-communism in Twentieth-century<br />

America: A Critical History (Santa Barbara, CA:<br />

Praeger, 2011), 144.<br />

6 Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976,<br />

Volume E-10, eds. Erin Mahan and Edward C.<br />

Keefer (Washington: Government Printing Office,<br />

2010), Preface.<br />

49 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 49


though, is overstated—at least insofar as<br />

the belief that they were motivated solely<br />

by the perception that communism as an<br />

ideology was an inherent danger. This is<br />

illustrated by the U.S. intervention in<br />

Bolivia and lack thereof in Argentina<br />

during the Nixon administration.<br />

In both Bolivia and Argentina there<br />

existed similar characteristics that would<br />

have satisfied the pretexts for intervention<br />

if ideology were the primary motivation.<br />

However, because the U.S. response to the<br />

situations in both countries proved to be<br />

more discerning, the “crusade against<br />

communism” thesis loses credibility.<br />

Instead, it is likely that ideology was not a<br />

primary concern. Rather, a confluence of<br />

factors influenced Nixon and Kissinger in<br />

their decision-making processes including<br />

economic interests, U.S. national security,<br />

and continued preeminence in the region.<br />

Insofar as the rise of popular politicians in<br />

Latin America threatened geopolitical<br />

order, Nixon-Kissinger policy sought to<br />

squash it. When less viable threats were<br />

identified, though, there existed more<br />

political and ideological liberty for Latin<br />

American leaders than many scholars<br />

identify.<br />

PRETEXTS TO THE BANZER<br />

REGIME IN BOLIVIA<br />

In April 1971, the United States<br />

supported a coup d’état in Bolivia that<br />

brought Hugo Banzer to power. The<br />

growing revolutionary fervor that justified<br />

this intervention in the eyes of the United<br />

States began with the non-democratic<br />

ascension of René Barrientos Ortuño to<br />

the presidency in 1964. He promised to<br />

realign Bolivia on the path of revolution<br />

that began in 1952 and later fizzled.<br />

Barrientos Ortuño believed that the<br />

previous 12-year regime of single party rule<br />

in the Nationalist Revolutionary Movement<br />

(MNR) had been led astray. 7 While<br />

Bolivia’s economy greatly benefited from<br />

Barrientos’ policies, he found few<br />

supporters particularly in the rural regions<br />

due to his continued efforts to subdue the<br />

labor force. After Barrientos’ untimely<br />

demise in 1969, General Alfredo Ovando<br />

Candia, who had been co-president with<br />

Barrientos until January 1966, assumed the<br />

presidency. 8<br />

Partially aligning himself with the<br />

populist contingent of the increasingly<br />

radical public, Ovando sought to end<br />

Bolivia’s favoritism of the U.S. by<br />

nationalizing Gulf Oil Company’s holdings.<br />

In a memo to the President dated<br />

September 26, 1969, Kissinger argued that<br />

Ovando’s presidency could threaten U.S.<br />

interests. In particular he stated that:<br />

Mining and oil<br />

investments…will<br />

undoubtedly be affected by<br />

the change of government.<br />

Gulf Oil, which has drawn<br />

fire in the Bolivian congress<br />

and press, will probably be<br />

the first to feel pressure at<br />

least in the form of requests<br />

for greater share of profits<br />

through higher taxes,<br />

royalties or creation of mixed<br />

companies. 9<br />

7 Dennis M. Hanratty & Rex A. Hudson, “A<br />

Country Study: Bolivia,” Country Studies, Library of<br />

Congress Federal Research Division, December<br />

1989.<br />

8 Ibid. The official story is that Barrientos died in a<br />

helicopter crash, but many of the details are still<br />

unknown. There is speculation that his death may<br />

have been part of some sort of plot, but this has not<br />

been proven.<br />

9 Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976,<br />

Volume E-10, eds. Erin Mahan and Edward C.<br />

Keefer (Washington: Government Printing Office,<br />

2010), Document 79.<br />

50 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 50


While correctly predicting that Gulf Oil<br />

holdings would be compromised by regime<br />

change, Kissinger’s predictions of potential<br />

outcomes proved much less severe. After<br />

Ovando elected to nationalize Gulf Oil<br />

holdings, Kissinger mentioned in another<br />

memo to President Nixon, “nationalization<br />

of Gulf, the largest foreign investment, was<br />

in many ways a ‘revolutionary’ symbol and<br />

a watershed…The nationalistic<br />

elements…moved suddenly.” 10 Kissinger’s<br />

memo expresses concern for U.S.<br />

“interests,” in this case economic, and also<br />

a concern for “revolution” and<br />

“nationalism,” but neither are directly<br />

rooted in the threat of communism. In<br />

this way, the origins of what would become<br />

the deteriorating political situation in<br />

Bolivia were not of ideological concern at<br />

the onset. Only insofar as they led to<br />

policies in Bolivia that threatened U.S.<br />

private interests did Kissinger choose to<br />

highlight them.<br />

Over the course of his presidency,<br />

Ovando’s oscillation between populist and<br />

nationalist rhetoric, while in some instances<br />

courting the right, further polarized the<br />

country and the military. This paved the<br />

way for the coup against him and the<br />

emergence of José Torres González.<br />

Torres was a left-wing general who took an<br />

even more aggressive stance against the<br />

United States. Although at times, Kissinger<br />

alluded to the fact that Torres might have<br />

pursued a moderate course with U.S.<br />

support, and that members of Torres’<br />

cabinet were fairly moderate. 11 During this<br />

time, the U.S. pursued a policy of selling<br />

tin to Bolivia from the U.S. government’s<br />

stockpile, which ended indefinitely on<br />

April 9, 1971. 12 Torres’ response shortly<br />

after was “favorable” according to a note<br />

from Kissinger to Nixon. The memo<br />

states, “[Torres] said he valued cordial<br />

relations with the U.S. ‘more than with any<br />

other country’ and he took your action as a<br />

clear sign of the U.S. concern for Bolivia<br />

and for its problems.” 13 What remains<br />

unclear is what later provoked Torres to<br />

expel the Peace Corps from Bolivia.<br />

Regardless, a transcribed conversation<br />

from two months later illustrates Kissinger<br />

and Nixon’s concerns regarding Bolivia,<br />

and potentially orchestrating a coup. The<br />

text reads:<br />

(Kissinger): We are having a<br />

major problem in Bolivia,<br />

too… I’ve told Karamessines<br />

to crank up an operation<br />

post-haste…<br />

(Nixon): What does<br />

Karamessines think we need?<br />

A coup?<br />

(Kissinger): We’ll see what<br />

we can, whether—in what<br />

context. They’re going to<br />

squeeze us out in another<br />

two months. They’ve already<br />

gotten rid of the Peace<br />

Corps, which is an asset, but<br />

now they want to get rid of<br />

USIA and military people…<br />

(Nixon): Remember, we gave<br />

those goddamn Bolivians<br />

that tin. 14<br />

10 Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976,<br />

Document 80.<br />

11 Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976,<br />

Document 95.<br />

12 Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976,<br />

Document 99.<br />

13 Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976,<br />

Document 98.<br />

14 Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976,<br />

Document 101.<br />

51 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 51


Weeks later, the CIA proposed potential<br />

covert actions that could be taken by the<br />

United States to topple the Torres regime.<br />

On August 19, 1971, NSC staffer Arnold<br />

Nachmanoff confirmed with Kissinger that<br />

opposition forces in the country’s capital,<br />

La Paz, were well aware of American<br />

support of a coup. 15 Ultimately, Colonel<br />

Hugo Banzer, who proved more favorable<br />

to U.S. interests, led a coup in August 1971<br />

that resulted in Torres’ exile.<br />

In light of all of this, the “dealing<br />

with the communist threat” paradigm<br />

seems nonexistent. The only mention of<br />

communism at all is Ambassador Ernest V.<br />

Siracusa’s remarks in June 1971 that failure<br />

to support opponents of the Torres<br />

regime, “might leave the door open for<br />

communists to gain yet another foothold in<br />

the Americas.” 16 Even so, the Ambassador<br />

mentions in a later memo that a coup may<br />

not be wise either, as the political climate<br />

of the situation is unstable, and a successful<br />

coup may simply result in the rise of<br />

another leftist leader. 17 In spite of this one<br />

remark, Nixon and Kissinger’s exchanges<br />

do not include any mention of<br />

communism. Therefore, in the context of<br />

Bolivia, the notion of a “communist<br />

crusade” is at best a secondary explanation.<br />

Compared to more significant U.S.<br />

interests like maintaining influential<br />

preeminence and the recuperation of<br />

financial losses due to the nationalization<br />

of various Bolivian industries, anticommunism<br />

was a less influential<br />

justification for the coup, if at all.<br />

Identifying the similarities and<br />

differences between the Bolivian<br />

experience during the Nixon<br />

15 Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976,<br />

Document 107.<br />

16 Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976,<br />

Document 76a.<br />

17 Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976,<br />

Document 106.<br />

administration and the Argentinian<br />

experience until Nixon’s resignation in<br />

1974, illuminates the nuances of the<br />

Nixon-Kissinger approach to U.S. foreign<br />

policy and its break with the traditional<br />

understanding of U.S. policy toward the<br />

region.<br />

ARGENTINA: THE 1973 COUP<br />

THAT NEVER WAS<br />

Richard Nixon was elected in the<br />

U.S. just as the Argentinian Revolution<br />

celebrated its third year. The Argentinian<br />

president at the time, Juan Carlos Onganía,<br />

had come to power after a coup that<br />

ousted center-left president Arturo<br />

Umberto Illia. 18 The regime proved to be<br />

an oppressive one that greatly limited civil<br />

liberties. Public approval for Onganía and<br />

his successors Roberto Levingston and<br />

Alejandro Lanusse, who remained in power<br />

until 1973, were at an all-time low. At the<br />

same time, the Argentinian political system<br />

was significantly impacted by the legacy of<br />

former president Juan Domingo Perón. 19<br />

Perón, who was forced into exile in<br />

1955, served as president of Argentina for<br />

two terms (1946-1955). 20 A difficult<br />

political figure to categorize in terms of<br />

ideology, Perón was known as a president<br />

who favored labor groups like the General<br />

Confederation of Labor (CGT), but also<br />

cited his admiration for the fascist regimes<br />

of Europe that fought in World War II.<br />

After his numerous political successes, he<br />

became a hero among Argentinians in spite<br />

of his eighteen years in exile. In fact<br />

Argentinians loved him more because of it.<br />

In exile, Perón remained an active critic of<br />

the military regimes that replaced him and<br />

18 Robert A. Potash. The Army & Politics in Argentina<br />

(Stanford, CA: Stanford UP, 1969).<br />

19 Ibid.<br />

20 Joseph A. Page. Perón̤: A Biography (NY: Random<br />

House, 1983).<br />

52 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 52


continued to build relationships from his<br />

temporary home in Franco’s Spain. His<br />

legacy in Argentina was a new political<br />

ideology specific to the country’s politics<br />

called Peronism. 21 It drew from Peron’s<br />

ideas to create a “third way” in the Cold<br />

War context that avoided the two extremes<br />

of capitalism and communism. The<br />

nostalgia built around the figure of Perón<br />

among Argentinian society is what led<br />

organizations like the Peronist Armed<br />

Forces (FAP), Montoneros, and People’s<br />

Revolutionary Army (ERP) to launch<br />

radical campaigns in his name against the<br />

repressive regimes of the Onganía,<br />

Levingston, and Lanusse. 22 These groups<br />

resorted to acts of terror as a result of the<br />

worsening sociopolitical situation.<br />

Peronists were presumed responsible for<br />

the bombing of the Sheraton Hotel in<br />

Buenos Aires. 23 The Montoneros resorted<br />

to similar acts of terror: in 1970 they<br />

kidnapped and executed former anti-<br />

Peronist president, Pedro Eugenio<br />

Aramburu. 24 The ERP was also responsible<br />

for waves of bombings and arson attacks in<br />

the early 1970s. 25 Perón’s degree of<br />

connection with these groups remains<br />

disputed, but the emergence of these<br />

groups is demonstrative of an increasingly<br />

radical population during this period.<br />

Perón later returned to Argentina<br />

in 1973 after a return to democracy. He<br />

was banned from participating in the<br />

elections, but his selection for President,<br />

Héctor Cámpara won by a sizeable margin.<br />

The perspective of the U.S. State<br />

21 James P. Brennan. Peronism and Argentina<br />

(Wilmington, DE: SR, 1998).<br />

22 Thomas C. Wright, Latin America in the Era of the<br />

Cuban Revolution (New York: Praeger, 1991).<br />

23 “Peronists Blamed in Hotel Bombing," The Free<br />

Lance-Star, October 17, 1972.<br />

24 James Ciment, World Terrorism: An Encyclopedia of<br />

Political Violence from Ancient times to the Post-9/11 Era<br />

(Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 2011), 167.<br />

25 Ibid.<br />

Department on Perón’s return is difficult<br />

to ascertain as declassified documents end<br />

in 1972. A telegram from that year,<br />

however, predicts that a triumphant return<br />

of Perón would be a positive development<br />

for Argentina, even though Perón’s<br />

ideology influenced the emergence of<br />

militant leftist groups. 26 The Nixon<br />

administration ultimately did not elect to<br />

intervene in Argentina. This idea is a clear<br />

demonstration of the administration’s<br />

nuanced approach in the region.<br />

In Bolivia, for example, Nixon<br />

expressed his concerns with guerilla<br />

movements that threatened Bolivian<br />

stability, so much so that he asked the<br />

Central Intelligence Agency (C.I.A.)<br />

director to look into it further. 27 On the<br />

other hand, in Argentina with a growing<br />

number of insurgent groups, some steeped<br />

deeply in Marxist ideology, there exists no<br />

mention in declassified State Department<br />

documents of the risks to Argentinian<br />

security (and therefore U.S. national<br />

security and interests) that these groups<br />

posed. Within the report that favors the<br />

return of Perón, for example, there is no<br />

indication as to how Perón’s return might<br />

affect these groups and their operations.<br />

This lack of concern for the militant left in<br />

Argentina represents nuanced<br />

understanding that although high profile<br />

acts of terrorism were occurring, the<br />

country was ultimately not at risk of a<br />

takeover by the militant left as much as<br />

Bolivia. In addition, it represents a careful<br />

analysis of the aims of both types of armed<br />

militant groups. Those found in Bolivia<br />

threatened the country’s stability, and were<br />

largely led by Che Guevara, who had<br />

26 Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976,<br />

Volume E-10, eds. Erin Mahan and Edward C.<br />

Keefer (Washington: Government Printing Office,<br />

2010), Document 76.<br />

27 Foreign Relations of the United States, 1969–1976,<br />

Document 92.<br />

53 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 53


already proven himself a successful<br />

commander in the realm of revolutionary<br />

uprisings. The FAP, ERP, and Montoneros<br />

in Argentina, however, were more likely<br />

associated with the fringes of the political<br />

system without any potential for complete<br />

disruption of the political order and the<br />

political system. Indeed, their violent<br />

actions were more reactionary than<br />

revolutionary.<br />

Additionally, Héctor José Cámpora<br />

decided to normalize diplomatic relations<br />

with Cuba immediately after his election.<br />

By this time Cuba was aligned with the<br />

Soviet bloc. The United States, however,<br />

took no recourse in Argentina. Therefore,<br />

it can be assumed that at the very least the<br />

U.S. tolerated Campora’s move. This<br />

supports the claim that the Nixon-<br />

Kissinger foreign policy mechanism was<br />

capable of acknowledging the fact that a<br />

country—at limited risk to communist<br />

insurgents—could successfully establish a<br />

relationship with another country under<br />

the Soviet umbrella while remaining<br />

outside of the Soviet sphere of influence.<br />

This calls into question the United<br />

States’ “global crusade against<br />

communism” thesis. If the U.S. had been<br />

concerned solely with the spread of the<br />

ideas of communism throughout Latin<br />

America, a different reality would have<br />

emerged. The U.S. would have been much<br />

less discriminate, eliminating any and all<br />

potential communist groups. This kind of<br />

indiscriminate squashing across the<br />

continent, however, is precisely what did<br />

not occur under Nixon. Similarly, a reversal<br />

of the proverb “the enemy of my enemy is<br />

my friend” to “the friend of my enemy is<br />

my enemy” would have been more<br />

apropos. 28 As Argentina normalized<br />

diplomatic relations with Cuba, the Nixon<br />

28 Kautạlya & L. N. Rangarajan. The Arthashastra<br />

(New Delhi: Penguin India, 1992).<br />

administration did not impose this<br />

doctrine. In this sense, the blanket of anticommunism<br />

and its application as the<br />

guiding principle behind all overt and<br />

covert foreign policy actions taken by the<br />

United States in Latin America—at least<br />

during the Nixon administration—has<br />

considerably lost steam.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

The countries that make up Latin<br />

America have understandable similarities,<br />

yet this often causes scholars to group the<br />

entire region as a single bloc. The reality is<br />

each country has its own idiosyncrasies,<br />

and U.S. foreign policy during the Cold<br />

War, as it relates to Latin American<br />

countries, illustrates these distinct qualities.<br />

In addition to the fact that context is often<br />

considered in policymaking, the ways in<br />

which foreign policy is enacted also<br />

depends on the leadership involved.<br />

Looking strictly at one president, Richard<br />

Nixon, it has become clear that even within<br />

the same larger global context, there were<br />

no preordained indicators that would<br />

precipitate a certain type of response.<br />

Yet in examining both Bolivia and<br />

Argentina, there are some noteworthy<br />

similarities in their respective narratives<br />

during the Nixon period. For one, Torres<br />

and Perón were similar leaders in that their<br />

ideologies were complex and could not<br />

simply be described as communist,<br />

socialist, or Marxist. In some ways this<br />

made their behavior unpredictable,<br />

particularly in the case of Torres. Second,<br />

both countries were in a relative state of<br />

sociopolitical turmoil during their<br />

respective leaders’ times in power (in this<br />

case after Perón’s exile). Finally, both<br />

exhibited some degree of repudiation for<br />

the United States. In the case of Torres,<br />

this manifested itself through his expulsion<br />

of the Peace Corps and nationalization of<br />

54 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 54


different assets. With Perón, this was<br />

expressed through an adherence to a “third<br />

way” foreign policy by seeking to forge a<br />

nonalignment path between the U.S. and<br />

Soviet Union. The result in both countries,<br />

however, was entirely different; in Bolivia<br />

the U.S. orchestrated a coup, and in<br />

Argentina the U.S. pursued a policy of<br />

economic assistance.<br />

The specific rationale that lies<br />

behind each of these decisions is cryptically<br />

represented in declassified correspondence<br />

between Nixon and Kissinger, but what the<br />

discrepancy indicates is that U.S. foreign<br />

policy towards Latin America during the<br />

Nixon administration was more fluid than<br />

is typically understood in scholarship. In<br />

addition, what is commonly thought to be<br />

the unitary thread in all foreign policy<br />

decisions during the Cold War, the specter<br />

of communism, did not play a significant<br />

role in the United States’ decision to act in<br />

Bolivia or not to act in Argentina. Instead,<br />

it was a confluence of factors. These<br />

examples demonstrate the calculated nature<br />

of the Nixon-Kissinger foreign policy<br />

agenda. By separating just two countries<br />

that are often analyzed as components of<br />

the Latin American bloc, more detailed and<br />

complex insights begin to take shape. This<br />

is indicative of one of the many pitfalls of<br />

aggregate foreign policy analysis—that is<br />

characterizing U.S. foreign policy as being<br />

consistent toward certain regional,<br />

economic, or ideological groupings. The<br />

fact is this form of grouping lacks the sort<br />

of local context required to understand the<br />

intricate nature of the U.S. foreign policy<br />

making mechanism.<br />

DYLAN HEYDEN is a first year M.A. student in<br />

International Relations. He graduated magna<br />

cum laude from the University of San Diego in<br />

2013, with a B.A. in International Relations &<br />

Spanish. Some of his prior research experiences<br />

include working for the University of San Diego's<br />

Trans-Border Institute analyzing rule of law in<br />

Mexico and U.S.-Mexico relations, and traveling<br />

to Nicaragua as a USD Changemaker Scholar to<br />

pursue his senior thesis.<br />

55 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 55


An Appraisal of the Joint<br />

Development Approach<br />

to the South China Sea<br />

Dispute<br />

Prospects and Challenges<br />

Guan Hui Lee<br />

The issue of overlapping sovereign<br />

claims over land and maritime<br />

resources in the South China Sea has<br />

been a major source of conflict between<br />

China, 1 Vietnam, the Philippines, Malaysia,<br />

Brunei and Indonesia. This analysis examines<br />

aspects of the joint development approach as<br />

a conflict prevention tool in the South China<br />

Sea dispute. It first seeks to explain the<br />

underlying logic behind joint development<br />

and the reasons why the approach was able to<br />

come to fruition from 2005 to 2008, in the<br />

form of a Joint Marine Seismic Undertaking<br />

(JMSU) between the state-owned oil<br />

corporations of China, Vietnam and the<br />

Philippines. It then proceeds to explain why<br />

the joint development approach used from<br />

2005 to 2008 is neither likely to be applied nor<br />

sufficient to resolve the dispute at present,<br />

given the recent development of affairs in the<br />

region by the parties involved. The analysis<br />

concludes with three conditions that are<br />

necessary for joint development to be a<br />

realistic conflict management strategy in the<br />

South China Sea.<br />

1 Throughout the paper, use of the term “China”<br />

pertains to both the People’s Republic of China and the<br />

Republic of China (Taiwan).<br />

THE PROBLEM<br />

The dispute over sovereign rights in<br />

the South China Sea is a long-standing one.<br />

This chiefly concerns the sovereignty of the<br />

Paracels and the Spratly Islands, as well as the<br />

waters around them. The People’s Republic of<br />

China and the Republic of China (Taiwan)<br />

share a common perspective in this dispute,<br />

but so far only Beijing has been actively<br />

dispatching navy patrol boats to the region.<br />

China bases its claims on historical grounds—<br />

specifically from maps dating back to 1947<br />

during the Kuomintang period which contain<br />

an eleven-dash line maritime boundary that<br />

effectively includes almost all of the South<br />

China Sea. However, China has never<br />

established effective control over the full<br />

extent of their claim. To date, China only<br />

effectively controls the Paracels, which were<br />

forcibly taken over from Vietnam in 1974, 2<br />

and parts of the Spratly Island group.<br />

However, the largest land feature in the<br />

Spratlys, Itu Aba, has always been<br />

administered by Taipei and not Beijing. 3<br />

Despite this, in May 2009, Beijing formally<br />

submitted a map with a nine-dash line 4 to the<br />

UN Commission on the Limits of the<br />

Continental Shelf (CLCS), defining areas<br />

included in the 1947 maps as “historic<br />

2 Congressional Research Service (CRS), “Maritime<br />

Territorial Disputes in East Asia: Issues for Congress,”<br />

CRS R42930, 23 January 2013.<br />

3 Ralf Emmers, “The Changing Power Distribution in<br />

the South China Sea: Implications for Conflict<br />

Management and Avoidance,” Political Science 62, No.<br />

118 (2010).<br />

4 Beijing revised the original eleven-dash line into a<br />

nine-dash line under Zhou Enlai after 1949. Claimed<br />

areas implied by both versions have remained<br />

essentially unchanged.<br />

56 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 56


waters.” 5 The nine-dash line not only includes<br />

all of the Paracels and the Spratlys, but also<br />

overlaps with Brunei’s claim of Louisa Reef,<br />

and reaches as far south as the eastern waters<br />

of Natuna Island, to which Indonesia stakes a<br />

claim. 6 Vietnam likewise lays claim to the<br />

Paracels and the Spratlys on both a historical<br />

basis and on current effective control (it<br />

controls 21 of the Spratly Islands). Malaysia,<br />

on the other hand, bases its claims on the<br />

natural prolongation of its continental shelves<br />

off Peninsula Malaysia and Borneo, which<br />

leads it to claim the southern islands in the<br />

Spratly archipelago. 7 In 2009, Vietnam and<br />

Malaysia submitted a joint claim to UN CLCS<br />

on areas of the South China Sea beyond their<br />

200 nautical mile exclusive economic zones<br />

(EEZ). It was believed that this sparked<br />

China’s response in the form of the nine-dash<br />

line. In June 2012, Vietnam’s National<br />

Assembly passed a Maritime Law that lays<br />

down formal claims to the Paracels and the<br />

Spratlys. 8<br />

Lastly, the Philippines’ claim is based<br />

on contiguity of the continental shelf, and a<br />

1978 Presidential Decree that declared<br />

sovereignty over what was called the<br />

“Kalayaan Island Group” (KIG), which<br />

5 Sam Bateman, “Regime building in the South China<br />

Sea— Current Situation and Outlook,” Australian<br />

Journal of Maritime and Ocean Affairs 3, No. 1 (2011), p.<br />

29.<br />

6 Thao Nguyen Hong and Ramses Amer, “A New<br />

Legal Arrangement for the South China Sea?” Ocean<br />

Development and International Law No. 40 (2009).<br />

7 Thao Nguyen Hong and Ramses Amer, “A New<br />

Legal Arrangement for the South China Sea?” Ocean<br />

Development and International Law No. 40 (2009).<br />

8 Congressional Research Service (CRS), “Maritime<br />

Territorial Disputes in East Asia: Issues for Congress,”<br />

CRS R42930, 23 January 2013.<br />

includes the east and northeast parts of the<br />

Spratlys. 9 The Philippines and China also<br />

compete over the sovereignty of Scarborough<br />

Shoal, a 150 square kilometers shoal that is<br />

situated to the northeast of the Spratlys. In<br />

terms of effective control, the Philippines<br />

currently occupies eight islands in the eastern<br />

Spratlys that were considered terra nullius. 10<br />

Fig. 1: Map of the South China Sea showing disputed<br />

claims by various countries, including PRC’s/ROC’s<br />

“nine-dash line” (Congressional Research Service<br />

(CRS), “Maritime Territorial Disputes in East<br />

Asia: Issues for Congress.” CRS R42930, 23<br />

January 2013)<br />

There are several elements of this<br />

dispute that are relevant to conflict<br />

management approaches. First, the South<br />

China Sea dispute is a complex web of<br />

bilateral and multilateral disputes. Some<br />

islands, like the Spratly Island group, are<br />

contested by China, Taiwan, the Philippines,<br />

Malaysia and Vietnam to various extents,<br />

whereas other islands, like the Paracels, are<br />

9 Leszek Buszynski, “The South China Sea Maritime<br />

Dispute: Legality, Power, and Conflict Prevention,”<br />

Asian Journal of Peacebuilding 1, No. 1 (2013).<br />

10 Ibid, 6.<br />

57 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 57


essentially just part of a bilateral dispute<br />

between China and Vietnam. This complicates<br />

conflict management because each friction<br />

point will then have to be dealt with<br />

individually, as not all countries have a stake<br />

(or an equal stake) in all of the disputed<br />

territories.<br />

Second, a major point of contention<br />

lies in whether some of the islands in question<br />

are legally recognized as “islands,” which are<br />

entitled to their own 200-mile EEZs, or<br />

whether they are merely “rocks,” which are<br />

given only 12nm territorial sea. 11 According to<br />

UN Convention on the Law of the Sea<br />

(UNCLOS) Article 21, Paragraph 3, “rocks<br />

which cannot sustain human habitation or<br />

economic life of their own shall have no<br />

exclusive economic zone or continental<br />

shelf.” 12 On this issue, China firmly believes<br />

that the islands in question are undeniably<br />

“islands” in the legal sense and hence generate<br />

their own EEZs, even though some of these<br />

islands are fully submerged at high tide and<br />

are incapable of sustaining economic life.<br />

Third, because not all countries have<br />

defined the boundaries of their claims in an<br />

official legal manner, UNCLOS cannot be<br />

used to resolve the existing disputes.<br />

UNCLOS stipulates that “countries with<br />

overlapping claims must resolve their claims by<br />

good faith negotiations,” 13 but with claims<br />

from each party not having been defined<br />

precisely, UNCLOS cannot be properly<br />

applied to the South China Sea situation.<br />

Moreover, China made a statutory declaration<br />

on 25 August 2006 to the UN Secretary<br />

General that it would not accept any<br />

international court or arbitration in disputes<br />

over sea delimitation or territory. 14 This means<br />

that the option of international arbitration as a<br />

conflict resolution tool is essentially a nonstarter.<br />

Competition over energy resources<br />

has been identified as a key driving force<br />

behind the current dispute. A preliminary<br />

Chinese survey in 1989 estimated that the<br />

Spratlys held deposits of 25 billion cubic<br />

meters of natural gas and 105 billion barrels<br />

of oil. 15 The US and Russia reported much<br />

lower estimates in their own surveys (15.8<br />

billion and 7.5 billion barrels of oil,<br />

respectively), but even those numbers serve to<br />

prove that the potential oil and gas resources<br />

under the South China Sea are extremely<br />

tempting to countries that border it. If<br />

resource exploitation is indeed a core<br />

underlying objective of the South China Sea<br />

claimants, one conflict management approach<br />

could be to reframe the issue from one of<br />

sovereignty to one of joint resource<br />

development and management. The next<br />

section examines the logic behind joint<br />

development in conflict management<br />

literature, and the brief use of this approach<br />

from 2005 to 2008 in the Spratlys by China,<br />

Vietnam and the Philippines, in the form of a<br />

tripartite agreement — Joint Marine Seismic<br />

Undertaking (JMSU).<br />

11 Thao Nguyen Hong and Ramses Amer, “A New<br />

Legal Arrangement for the South China Sea?” Ocean<br />

Development and International Law No. 40 (2009), p. 340.<br />

12 Ralf Emmers, “The Prospects for Managing and<br />

Resolving Conflict in the South China Sea,” Harvard<br />

Asia Quarterly XII (3&4) (Winter 2010), p. 16.<br />

13 Ibid, italics mine.<br />

14 David Scott, “Conflict Irresolution in the South<br />

China Sea,” Asian Survey 52, No. 6 (Nov/Dec 2012), p.<br />

1022.<br />

15 Craig Snyder, “The Implications of Hydrocarbon<br />

Development on the South China Sea,” International<br />

Journal 52, No. 1 (Winter 1996/1997).<br />

58 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 58


THE LOGIC OF JOINT<br />

DEVELOPMENT AND ITS<br />

APPLICATION IN THE SOUTH<br />

CHINA SEA<br />

The theory and practice of conflict<br />

management is replete with notions of joint<br />

development. William Zartman makes an<br />

oblique reference to joint development when<br />

he notes that the key to successful preventive<br />

diplomacy is using the right tactics to change<br />

relevant stakes and attitudes. 16 According to<br />

him, preventive diplomacy should change the<br />

perception of stakes from zero-sum to<br />

positive sum, and the attitude of conflict<br />

parties from conflictual to accommodative. In<br />

the case of territorial disputes, Zartman<br />

asserts that preventive diplomacy should shift<br />

the nature of claims from territorial<br />

possession to “some lesser form of<br />

concern.” 17 In the case of the South China<br />

Sea, viewing the conflict as a joint<br />

development puzzle instead of a zero-sum<br />

sovereignty contest addresses the issue of<br />

access to resources that sovereignty claims are<br />

presumed to entail. In addition, it also avoids<br />

stoking fear in non-claimant countries like<br />

Japan, India and the US, who would be<br />

concerned about freedom of navigation in the<br />

South China Sea if the dispute were to be<br />

framed as a sovereignty issue.<br />

Zou Keyuan defines the<br />

characteristics of joint development with a<br />

definition given by the British Institute of<br />

International and Comparative Law:<br />

16 William I. Zartman, Preventive Negotiation: Avoiding<br />

Conflict Escalation (Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield,<br />

2001), p. 7.<br />

17 Ibid, p. 12.<br />

(a) is an arrangement between two<br />

countries; 18<br />

(b) is usually concerned with an<br />

overlapping maritime area;<br />

(c) can be used as a provisional<br />

arrangement pending the settlement of<br />

the boundary delimitation disputes<br />

between the countries concerned;<br />

(d) is designed to jointly develop the<br />

mineral resources in the disputed area or<br />

a defined area shared by two countries. 19<br />

This is particularly useful to the South<br />

China Sea because joint development does<br />

not pay attention to boundary delimitation<br />

claims among disputants. Hence, countries<br />

that participate in joint development need not<br />

worry about the possibility of having their<br />

sovereignty claims weakened. 20<br />

Sam Bateman defines joint<br />

development as “a functional approach that<br />

exploits the common interests of claimant<br />

countries,” 21 and lists steps by which joint<br />

development can be achieved: identifying a<br />

particular function to cooperate in; defining<br />

the area of joint development; finding a<br />

formula to share costs and resources;<br />

establishing a management body. Craig Snyder<br />

further explains what these “common<br />

interests” may be. Commercial benefits and<br />

18 This is because there has yet been an ongoing, fully<br />

functional multilateral joint development arrangement<br />

that has been established in international law.<br />

19 Zou Keyuan, “Joint Development in the South<br />

China Sea: A New Approach,” The International Journal of<br />

Marine and Coastal Law 21, No. 1 (2006), p. 90.<br />

20 Mark J. Valencia, “In Response to Robert Beckman,”<br />

RSIS Commentaries 53 (2007).<br />

21 Sam Bateman, “Regime building in the South China<br />

Sea— Current Situation and Outlook,” Australian<br />

Journal of Maritime and Ocean Affairs 3, No. 1 (2011), p.<br />

30.<br />

59 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 59


technology transfer, according to him, can be<br />

strong incentives for countries to engage in<br />

joint development. He asserts that if “the<br />

desire to develop hydrocarbon resources<br />

outweighs the desire to win a boundary<br />

dispute,” 22 a joint development agreement is<br />

an inherently feasible conflict resolution tool.<br />

There have been instances where joint<br />

development was used in Southeast Asia to<br />

mitigate resource disputes. The Timor Gap<br />

Treaty in 1989 between Indonesia and<br />

Australia was an extensive case of joint<br />

development, where both countries<br />

established twelve separate joint development<br />

zones for each area of overlapping claims in<br />

the Timor Sea. 23 Malaysia and Thailand agreed<br />

in 1990 to a Joint Development area to<br />

manage natural gas reserves in disputed waters<br />

in the Gulf of Thailand. 24 In 1992, Vietnam<br />

and Malaysia signed a memorandum of<br />

understanding over oil exploration and<br />

production in the Gulf of Thailand. 25<br />

The 2005 JMSU was the first attempt<br />

at a multilateral joint development agreement<br />

in the South China Sea. Instead of a<br />

government-level memorandum of<br />

understanding, it was a commercial agreement<br />

between the state-owned oil corporations of<br />

China, Vietnam and the Philippines —<br />

CNOOC, PetroVietnam, and PNOC-EC,<br />

respectively. 26 JMSU dictated protocols with<br />

regard to seismic exploration of hydrocarbons<br />

in specific parts of the South China Sea, and<br />

stated that the three parties “jointly owned”<br />

data and information acquired through such<br />

seismic work. 27 However, after “the<br />

Philippines… ha[d] made breathtaking<br />

concessions in agreeing to the area of study,<br />

including parts of its own continental shelf<br />

not even claimed by China and Vietnam,” 28<br />

Philippine legislators protested against the<br />

continuation of JMSU, claiming that JMSU<br />

did not conform to Philippine state laws on<br />

oil exploration within Philippine territory. The<br />

agreement was hence allowed to expire in July<br />

2008.<br />

Although no actual exploitation was<br />

conducted under JMSU, the seismic surveys<br />

conducted under JMSU would qualify as joint<br />

development. After JMSU expired in 2008,<br />

the Philippines under President Benigno<br />

Aquino suggested a similar proposal — Zone<br />

of Peace, Freedom, Friendship and<br />

Cooperation (ZoPFFC). Alluding to the<br />

concept of joint development, the ZoPFFC<br />

proposed by the Philippines would<br />

“segregate” disputed areas from non-disputed<br />

areas, and “establish a joint agency to manage<br />

seabed resources and fisheries” in the<br />

22 Craig Snyder, “The Implications of Hydrocarbon<br />

Development on the South China Sea,” International<br />

Journal 52, No. 1 (Winter 1996/1997), p. 152.<br />

23 Zou Keyuan, “Joint Development in the South<br />

China Sea: A New Approach,” The International Journal of<br />

Marine and Coastal Law 21, No. 1 (2006), p. 96.<br />

24 David Scott, “Conflict Irresolution in the South<br />

China Sea,” Asian Survey 52, No. 6 (Nov/Dec 2012), p.<br />

1040.<br />

25 Craig Snyder, “The Implications of Hydrocarbon<br />

Development on the South China Sea,” International<br />

Journal 52, No. 1 (Winter 1996/1997), p. 154.<br />

26 Thao Nguyen Hong and Ramses Amer, “A New<br />

Legal Arrangement for the South China Sea?” Ocean<br />

Development and International Law No. 40 (2009), p. 343.<br />

27 Christina E. Tecson, “Exploring Exploration: Fitting<br />

the Joint Marine Seismic Undertaking and Oil<br />

Exploration Laws into the Mold of Section 2, Article<br />

XII of the 1987 Constitution,” Ateneo Law Journal 55,<br />

No. 149 (2010), p. 187.<br />

28 Barry Wain, “Manila’s Bungle in the South China<br />

Sea,” Far Eastern Economic Review 171 (January/February<br />

2008), p. 45.<br />

60 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 60


disputed areas. 29 However, this idea did not<br />

come to fruition because the boundaries<br />

claimed by each country have not all been<br />

precisely defined, and hence it is impossible to<br />

delineate ‘disputed areas’ from ‘non-disputed<br />

areas.’ 30 Moreover, China’s stance was<br />

extremely critical of the Philippines’ proposal,<br />

as the state-run media called it a “trick<br />

designed to encourage the United States to<br />

meddle in the South China Sea.” 31<br />

THE LOW LIKELIHOOD OF<br />

JOINT DEVELOPMENT IN<br />

TODAY’S CONTEXT<br />

Given the ostensible benefits of joint<br />

development in the South China Sea, why has<br />

there not been sustainable progress in that<br />

direction? This paper argues that the current<br />

political conditions in the South China Sea<br />

have not met the prerequisites of the joint<br />

development approach to become a<br />

sustainable solution for the region.<br />

Specifically, this paper will discuss three key<br />

reasons that present as obstacles to joint<br />

development: (1) the growing power<br />

asymmetry between the disputants; (2) the<br />

lack of an institutionalized mechanism to<br />

enforce and regulate joint development, in<br />

particular the inability of ASEAN to fill that<br />

capacity; (3) the association with identity<br />

politics and nationalism.<br />

First, the growing power asymmetry in<br />

China’s favor strengthens the notion of a<br />

29 Ian Storey, “ASEAN and the South China Sea:<br />

Movement in Lieu of Progress,” China Brief 12, No. 9<br />

(27 April 2012).<br />

30 Congressional Research Service (CRS), “Maritime<br />

Territorial Disputes in East Asia: Issues for Congress,”<br />

CRS R42930, 23 January 2013, p. 12.<br />

31 Ibid 28, p. 10.<br />

security dilemma. From 2000 to 2011, China<br />

has increased its announced defense budget<br />

by an average of 11.8 percent annually. 32 The<br />

PLA Navy has also expanded a major base on<br />

Hainan Island for submarines and vessels,<br />

signaling its increasing military presence in the<br />

South China Sea. China’s actions naturally<br />

alarmed its Southeast Asian neighbors, who<br />

have also started strengthening their military<br />

capabilities, thus raising the specter of a<br />

security dilemma. Vietnam, for example,<br />

announced in 2010 its purchase of six Russian<br />

Kilo-class submarines. 33<br />

As a result of the growing asymmetry<br />

in military forces, there is a prevailing<br />

perception among the Southeast Asian<br />

disputants that China is seeking to gain<br />

control over the disputed islands by force.<br />

Recent actions taken by the Chinese in the<br />

region have lent credence to this perception.<br />

For instance, Vietnam has alleged on several<br />

occasions that Chinese maritime surveillance<br />

vessels have severed the exploration cables of<br />

Vietnamese survey ships. 34 The 2012<br />

Scarborough Shoal standoff between China<br />

and the Philippines further indicates the<br />

tendency for military presence in the region to<br />

escalate the conflict. The Chinese motivation<br />

behind these actions is presumably to<br />

strengthen its hand on legal grounds. Since<br />

“first discovery” is not a sufficient basis to<br />

32 Congressional Research Service (CRS), “Maritime<br />

Territorial Disputes in East Asia: Issues for Congress,”<br />

CRS R42930, 23 January 2013.<br />

33 Ralf Emmers, “The Changing Power Distribution in<br />

the South China Sea: Implications for Conflict<br />

Management and Avoidance,” Political Science 62, No.<br />

118 (2010).<br />

34 Leszek Buszynski, “The South China Sea Maritime<br />

Dispute: Legality, Power, and Conflict Prevention,”<br />

Asian Journal of Peacebuilding 1, No. 1 (2013).<br />

61 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 61


claim legal sovereignty, China has been<br />

attempting to establish ‘administrative and<br />

physical’ control over the disputed islands in<br />

order to demonstrate sovereignty. To illustrate<br />

a case in point, Indonesia lost an International<br />

Court arbitration against Malaysia over the<br />

Ligitan and Sipadan islands in 2002 because it<br />

failed to protest the construction of<br />

lighthouses by Malaysia since 1963. 35<br />

The absence of a security guarantee to<br />

the weaker parties of the South China Sea<br />

dispute is inimical to the joint development<br />

approach. The logic of joint development<br />

assumes adequate ‘goodwill’ between the<br />

disputants to negotiate and follow rules<br />

established by a certain joint development<br />

agreement. However, without a security<br />

guarantee, weaker parties are not sufficiently<br />

assured that the stronger parties are<br />

committed to a joint development approach,<br />

since it may be feasible for the stronger<br />

parties to achieve complete victory by<br />

exercising military force. In fact, China’s<br />

actions post-JMSU have fed perceptions<br />

contrary to the spirit of joint development.<br />

Second, there is a notable lack of a<br />

supranational authority to establish and<br />

enforce the terms of joint development. The<br />

Association of Southeast Asian Nations<br />

(ASEAN), a potential candidate in this regard,<br />

has been particularly unhelpful so far. Because<br />

ASEAN’s operations rely on an informal style<br />

of diplomacy and consensus building, it is<br />

often considered too weak to institutionalize<br />

negotiations under a joint development<br />

framework, let alone enforce the terms of a<br />

35 Thao Nguyen Hong and Ramses Amer, “A New<br />

Legal Arrangement for the South China Sea?” Ocean<br />

Development and International Law No. 40 (2009).<br />

possible joint development outcome. 36 Huge<br />

disagreements between ASEAN states have<br />

also impeded the viability of ASEAN to enter<br />

as an impartial actor in this dispute.<br />

Cambodia, in particular, adopts the Chinese<br />

stance on this issue, and rejects any<br />

“institutionalization” of the South China Sea<br />

dispute. 37 Opinion among ASEAN members<br />

on this issue has been so divisive that the<br />

2012 ASEAN Foreign Ministers Meeting,<br />

chaired by Cambodia, failed to produce a joint<br />

communiqué because of major disagreements<br />

over a unified stance on the issue.<br />

Because there is no suitable candidate<br />

to administer joint development agreements<br />

on the South China Sea issue, it is difficult to<br />

envision joint development on the issue going<br />

beyond the level achieved by JMSU. It is<br />

important to note here that JMSU succeeded<br />

in part because it was a commercial<br />

agreement, which entailed that it did not<br />

invoke the application of international law<br />

that regulates interstate behavior. Important<br />

details of joint development, such as the<br />

delimitation of the joint development area,<br />

taxation of revenues generated by joint<br />

development, and a dispute settlement<br />

mechanism, cannot be established without the<br />

institution of a governing body. Without a<br />

governing body, countries can jeopardize<br />

existing joint development agreements<br />

according to their individual state interests.<br />

Third, the emphasis on a nationalistic<br />

element to the South China Sea dispute post-<br />

36 Ioana-Bianca Berna, “Managing Intra-Regional<br />

Conflicts in Southeast Asia: The Case of the South<br />

China Sea,” Journal of Defense Resource Management 4, No.<br />

2 (2014).<br />

37 Ian Storey, “ASEAN and the South China Sea:<br />

Movement in Lieu of Progress,” China Brief 12, No. 9<br />

(27 April 2012), p. 12.<br />

62 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 62


JMSU has demonstrated that the conflict is<br />

still being viewed through the lens of national<br />

sovereignty. As mentioned earlier, the premise<br />

of joint development is to induce perceptual<br />

change in disputants, from viewing the<br />

conflict as a zero-sum sovereignty contest to a<br />

positive-sum resource allocation problem.<br />

However, the prominence of nationalistic<br />

sentiment on the issue in recent years has<br />

invited the participation of the general public<br />

in the various claimant countries, and<br />

effectively escalated the conflict. At present,<br />

the prospects of successful joint development<br />

are dim, because of the association of the<br />

sovereignty claims with national pride, which<br />

has increasingly solidified the framing of the<br />

problem as that of national sovereignty<br />

instead of resource allocation. To name a<br />

precedent, the joint development agreement<br />

between China and Japan on the<br />

Chunxiao/Shirakaba gas fields in 2008 has<br />

been jettisoned by nationalistic Chinese public<br />

opinion, which deemed the agreement as<br />

“betraying the national interests and forfeiting<br />

China’s sovereignty.” 38<br />

Aside from this, the professional<br />

autonomy of the PLA Navy allows it to frame<br />

its own operating goals within the broad<br />

policy parameters set by the Chinese<br />

leadership. 39 This means that there is a side<br />

incentive for the Chinese military to pursue<br />

the South China Sea dispute as a national<br />

sovereignty issue to an extent that may be<br />

outside the control of the Chinese leadership<br />

bureaucracy.<br />

38 Thao Nguyen Hong and Ramses Amer, “A New<br />

Legal Arrangement for the South China Sea?” Ocean<br />

Development and International Law No. 40 (2009), p. 344.<br />

39 Leszek Buszynski, “The South China Sea Maritime<br />

Dispute: Legality, Power, and Conflict Prevention,”<br />

Asian Journal of Peacebuilding 1, No. 1 (2013).<br />

The idea of a joint development<br />

approach cannot move forward when national<br />

sovereignty is regarded by conflict parties as<br />

their utmost priority. In fact, the JMSU failed<br />

to be a sustainable solution because there is a<br />

strong tendency among claimants that joint<br />

development “should not be attempted in an<br />

area which a claimant believes to be its own,<br />

and should only be attempted in areas outside<br />

its claims.” 40 A ‘without prejudice’ clause<br />

seems to be a precondition for joint<br />

development. Without the provision of such a<br />

clause, any attempt to cooperate will be seen<br />

as a ‘sell-out’ on a disputant’s sovereignty<br />

claims. 41<br />

STEPS TO ENHANCE THE<br />

FEASIBILITY OF AN EVENTUAL<br />

JOINT DEVELOPMENT<br />

APPROACH<br />

The first two obstacles outlined in the<br />

previous section point to the need of an<br />

institutionalized regime to act as a security<br />

guarantee for conflict parties to participate in<br />

joint development. For that to be a reality,<br />

claimant countries need to “freeze” their<br />

existing territorial claims and commit to the<br />

concept of joint development. 42 The<br />

purported rationale behind China’s increased<br />

military assertiveness in the South China Sea<br />

is that it sees room for conflict escalation at<br />

40 Zou Keyuan, “Joint Development in the South<br />

China Sea: A New Approach,” The International Journal of<br />

Marine and Coastal Law 21, No. 1 (2006), p. 102.<br />

41 Mark J. Valencia, “In Response to Robert Beckman,”<br />

RSIS Commentaries 53 (2007).<br />

42 Ralf Emmers, “The Changing Power Distribution in<br />

the South China Sea: Implications for Conflict<br />

Management and Avoidance,” Political Science 62, No.<br />

118 (2010), p. 131.<br />

63 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 63


little cost to itself. However, one could also<br />

note that there are limits to such behavior, as<br />

China is aware of its dependence on regional<br />

and international economic order, and hence<br />

would not at present ‘cross the Rubicon’ by<br />

attempting to militarily force a resolution of<br />

this dispute in its favor. Judging from this<br />

fact, increased military balancing by the<br />

United States may force China to reevaluate<br />

its costs and benefits from its current actions<br />

and hence induce a more amenable position in<br />

China. However, there is also the danger of<br />

descending into a brinkmanship contest that<br />

results in further escalation of the conflict.<br />

Therefore, a delicate balance of military and<br />

diplomatic measures needs to be carried out<br />

on the part of the United States.<br />

Zou suggests the establishment of a<br />

supranational “Spratly Management<br />

Authority” to regulate joint development in<br />

the Spratly Islands. 43 In particular, he points<br />

out that Rifleman Bank is an ideal place to<br />

begin joint development, as it falls outside the<br />

200-mile EEZ of Vietnam, outside the<br />

continental shelf limits of Brunei and<br />

Malaysia, and outside of the Philippine claim<br />

of the “Kalayaan Island Group.” This is,<br />

nevertheless, subject to China’s and Vietnam’s<br />

‘compromise’, as Vietnam currently occupies<br />

Rifleman Bank, whereas China claims<br />

sovereignty over it. Mark Valencia et al. also<br />

proposes a regional organization that “grants<br />

permits for exploration and joint<br />

development, and would direct financial<br />

resources of claimants into a common fund to<br />

promote joint exploration efforts.” 44<br />

43 Ibid 39, p. 96.<br />

44 Leszek Buszynski, “The South China Sea Maritime<br />

Dispute: Legality, Power, and Conflict Prevention,”<br />

Asian Journal of Peacebuilding 1, No. 1 (2013), p. 55.<br />

These proposals seem far-fetched<br />

without the appropriate change in perceptions<br />

of stakes and attitudes. More support can be<br />

given to official or Track II workshops that<br />

discuss the establishment of functional<br />

frameworks on the South China Sea issue. For<br />

example, Indonesia has hosted informal<br />

Workshops on Managing Potential Conflicts<br />

in the South China Sea (SCSW) since the early<br />

1990s. 45 The Council for Security Cooperation<br />

in the Asia Pacific (CSCAP) Study Group on<br />

Maritime Security has also been a informal<br />

multilateral platform where representatives<br />

from each country have highlighted issues<br />

indicative of their country’s main concerns in<br />

the South China Sea dispute, including<br />

information sharing and law enforcement. 46<br />

While ASEAN may not be the ideal regional<br />

organization to preside over this dispute, it<br />

can contribute to confidence building<br />

measures (CBMs) on an official level, such as<br />

in maritime security dialogues under the<br />

ASEAN Regional Forum or the ASEAN<br />

Defense Ministers’ Meeting Plus (ADMM+). 47<br />

Nguyen Dang Thang advocates that joint<br />

development can adopt a neo-functionalist<br />

approach, first taking place in a fisheries<br />

arrangement before proceeding to an oil and<br />

gas arrangement, with the latter considered as<br />

45 Mikael Weissmann, “The South China Sea Conflict<br />

and Sino-ASEAN Relations: A Study in Conflict<br />

Prevention and Peace Building,” Asian Perspectives 34,<br />

No. 3 (2010).<br />

46 Council for Security Cooperation in the Asia Pacific<br />

(CSCAP), “1st Meeting of the CSCAP Study Group on<br />

Maritime Security,” Australian Journal of Maritime and<br />

Ocean Affairs 5, No. 2 (2013).<br />

47 Ioana-Bianca Berna, “Managing Intra-Regional<br />

Conflicts in Southeast Asia: The Case of the South<br />

China Sea,” Journal of Defense Resource Management 4, No.<br />

2 (2014).<br />

64 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 64


a more sensitive area of cooperation. 48 In sum,<br />

these confidence building measures should be<br />

regarded as a first step towards a realistic<br />

conception of joint development in the South<br />

China Sea.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

The concept of “joint development” is<br />

a tempting option for a potential resolution of<br />

the South China Sea sovereignty issues, given<br />

that it has been attempted previously in other<br />

regional disputes. However, in order for joint<br />

development to come to fruition, claimant<br />

countries have to temporarily “freeze” or<br />

suspend their zero-sum sovereignty claims<br />

and commit to a positive-sum resource<br />

allocation problem. Unfortunately, one has yet<br />

to see this happen in the context of the South<br />

China Sea, especially with China’s growing<br />

naval power, and the continued lack of a<br />

supranational authority presiding over the<br />

issue. Various measures can contribute to this<br />

mindset change. ASEAN can be a vehicle for<br />

establishing CBMs on an official level, or even<br />

in the form of closed-door meetings, where<br />

disputants are deemed to be more honest<br />

about their priorities and interests. A neofunctionalist<br />

approach, for example, by<br />

starting with a fisheries arrangement before<br />

proceeding to an oil and gas arrangement,<br />

should also be considered in the hope of<br />

eventually leading to the settlement of core<br />

disputes.<br />

GUAN HUI LEE is a first-year Master's<br />

student majoring in International<br />

Relations. He received his undergraduate<br />

degree in IR from<br />

Peking University<br />

in 2013. His<br />

academic interests<br />

include U.S.<br />

foreign policy,<br />

political theory<br />

and U.S.-China<br />

foreign relations.<br />

His senior thesis<br />

compared aspects<br />

of Reaganite neoconservatism and the<br />

2010 Tea Party conservative movement.<br />

He is currently interning at the National<br />

Committee on U.S.-China Relations, where<br />

he has the opportunity to interact with<br />

like-minded people in his field.<br />

48 Thang Nguyen Dang, “Fisheries Cooperation in the<br />

South China Sea and the (Ir)relevance of the<br />

Sovereignty Question,” Asian Journal of International Law<br />

2 (2012).<br />

65 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 65


Is Sustained Economic<br />

Growth in Russia’s<br />

Future?<br />

Joel Alexander<br />

Russia’s economic history is one told<br />

through booms and busts. Since<br />

the collapse of the Soviet Union,<br />

Russia has witnessed growth intermitted by<br />

crises in 1998 and 2008. Each crisis wiped<br />

out the preceding economic progress,<br />

ultimately keeping Russia in a state of<br />

overall stagnation. From 1991 to 2008,<br />

Russia’s economy transformed from a<br />

communist economy to a fledging capitalist<br />

economy. Despite its transformation,<br />

however, Russia’s economy battles with the<br />

prototypical problem of an authoritarian<br />

structure—achieving sustained growth.<br />

However, growth in Russia is not about<br />

overcoming the remnants of its communist<br />

society, nor is it about adopting liberal<br />

capitalism. Jack A. Goldstone addresses<br />

this problem in his essay “Efflorescences<br />

and economic growth in world history:<br />

rethinking the "rise of the west" and the<br />

industrial revolution,” where he reexamines<br />

the distinction between pre-modern and<br />

modern economies, ultimately calling for a<br />

separation of liberal Western economics<br />

from modern economic growth.<br />

Goldstone critiques the normative<br />

approach of analyzing economic growth in<br />

world history that specifies two norms—<br />

modern economic growth stemming from<br />

Western nations and pre-modern<br />

unsustainable growth from non-Western<br />

nations. This distinction rests on the<br />

assumption that pre-modern societies<br />

could not achieve sustained growth<br />

because of structural and political problems<br />

in how those countries were managed.<br />

Moreover, this approach claims that<br />

Western nations were better suited<br />

structurally, politically, and culturally to<br />

evolve and achieve sustained economic<br />

growth, thus making them modern<br />

economies. Goldstone purports that such a<br />

normative approach is a fallacy. Employing<br />

a historical analysis, he asserts that every<br />

nation goes through periods of growth,<br />

stability, stagnation, and crisis. He<br />

proscribes their ability to achieve sustained<br />

growth to their own unique cultural<br />

contents and organizational frameworks—<br />

or their own “peculiar local phenomena,”<br />

—which allows a nation to better utilize its<br />

human capital and resources to achieve<br />

sustained growth. To arrive at this analysis,<br />

Goldstone uses the theoretical lenses of<br />

efflorescence. Goldstone’s notion of<br />

“efflorescence” is a more<br />

multidimensional, holistic concept of<br />

economic growth, compared to the binary<br />

theories of growth that postulated a zerosum<br />

growth or no-growth environment.<br />

Moreover, efflorescence allows for the<br />

equalizing of both Eastern and Western<br />

nations, refuting that the liberal Western<br />

economic model definition of economic<br />

growth. By seeing all pre-modern history as<br />

punctuated by efflorescences, Goldstone<br />

argued, “growth and prosperity were not<br />

monopolies of the modern or Western (or<br />

even "capitalist") worlds.” 1 If all economies<br />

went through periods of efflorescence, and<br />

it was a “peculiar local phenomena” that<br />

allowed them to achieve sustained growth,<br />

the question is no longer how much a<br />

country emulates Western liberal<br />

economies, but rather, which intrinsic<br />

aspects of a country will promote a<br />

transition away from unsustainable growth<br />

to modern economic growth?<br />

1 Jack A. Goldstone, “Efflorescences and Economic<br />

Growth in World History: Rethinking The ‘Rise Of<br />

The West’ and The Industrial Revolution,” Journal of<br />

World History 13, no. 2, (2002), 47, 377-378.<br />

66 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 66


This lens is particularly helpful<br />

when understanding Russia’s political<br />

economy in boom and bust cycles. This<br />

paper clarifies that Russia witnessed<br />

periods of efflorescence after the 1998<br />

Asian financial crisis and then again after<br />

the 2008 global financial crisis. Specifically,<br />

there were factors of Russia’s economy<br />

that promoted efflorescence and those that<br />

stifled efflorescence, leading to<br />

unsustainable growth. After transitioning<br />

from a communist society to a semicapitalist<br />

economy, Russia experienced a<br />

period of economic growth, which was<br />

ultimately undermined by its Oligarchconducive<br />

policies. Later its economic<br />

growth advanced and then declined<br />

because of the economy’s dependence on<br />

natural resources, namely oil and gas. 2<br />

Then, in 2010, Russia witnessed a rise of a<br />

peculiar phenomenon. The phenomenon<br />

stemmed from a mixture of Russia’s<br />

growing middle class and the demands they<br />

imposed on the political system, and<br />

Russia’s apparent top-down approach to<br />

innovation and investment in its human<br />

capital. First, this paper will reanalyze<br />

Russia’s political economy through an<br />

explanation and exploration of Goldstone's<br />

efflorescence theory. It will then clarify the<br />

drivers for and against sustained<br />

efflorescence in Russia, which stem from<br />

the country’s own peculiar local<br />

characteristics rather than from the<br />

absence of liberal capital reforms.<br />

GOLDSTONE’S EFFLORESCENCE<br />

THEORY<br />

In his seminal work on<br />

Efflorescence Goldstone makes a<br />

distinction between the historical<br />

2 This economic phenomenon is known as “Dutch<br />

Disease,” and will be enumerated on at later points<br />

in the analysis.<br />

understanding of modern and pre-modern<br />

nations. This is important for Goldstone<br />

because it allows for the “rethinking of the<br />

‘rise of the West,’” which takes the strength<br />

from those advocates that assume<br />

modernization has a Western façade. By<br />

studying economic growth from the 10 th<br />

century to the early 18 th century, Goldstone<br />

disproves the historical fallacy of the rise of<br />

the West. He finds that the trends<br />

observed in Europe which were “proof of<br />

‘early modern’ character,” such as technical<br />

innovations, and extensive trade networks,<br />

to name a few, were also manifested<br />

outside Europe prior to the eighteenth<br />

century. 3 There is no sufficient connection<br />

between the “rise of the West” and<br />

sustained economic growth. Goldstone<br />

begins by inventing the neologism<br />

“efflorescence” and deconstructing our<br />

customary methods of conceptualizing<br />

growth.<br />

In the absence of an economic<br />

crisis, there may be growth, stagnation, or<br />

stability; each phase is cyclical and as<br />

important as the next. Efflorescence is the<br />

converse of a crisis: “a relatively sharp,<br />

often unexpected upturn in significant<br />

demographic and economic indices, usually<br />

accompanied by political<br />

expansion…institution building, and<br />

cultural synthesis”. 4 Without the distinction<br />

of efflorescence, the toolkit for<br />

understanding economic growth stems<br />

from two classifications. First, there is<br />

Kuznetzian/Schumpeterian Growth where<br />

growth is defined by internally driven and<br />

self-sustaining rapid increases in indices<br />

such as income per capita, and total output.<br />

This process occurs through creative<br />

destruction, whereby older technologies and<br />

firms are replaced by more efficient<br />

3 Goldstone, “Efflorescences and Economic<br />

Growth in World History: Rethinking The ‘Rise Of<br />

The West’ and The Industrial Revolution,” 6.<br />

4 Ibid, 9.<br />

67 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 67


substitutes. Second, there is<br />

Extensive/Smithian Growth, which is<br />

growth that lacks significant technological<br />

improvements, as in the Kuznetzian<br />

model. Instead, higher incomes per capita<br />

and total output increase because of a<br />

country’s comparative specialization<br />

expanding trade and the mobility of<br />

specific resources. According to the theory,<br />

this growth is not sustainable and will<br />

eventually be counterbalanced by the<br />

leveling off population growth, and/or the<br />

depletion of resources—known as<br />

Malthusian constraints. Goldstone opines<br />

that those two distinctions of growth<br />

create a zero and one binary of growth or<br />

stagnation. Efflorescence, can account for<br />

a country’s growth that does not fit the<br />

characterizations provided by only an<br />

Schumpeterian-type or Smithian-type of<br />

growth.<br />

Equipped with Goldstone’s theory,<br />

this paper re-contextualizes the story of<br />

Russia as one of various efflorescences,<br />

which have cyclically emerged and then<br />

contracted. Analyzing Russia through the<br />

lens of efflorescence theory can help<br />

identify the various reasons why<br />

efflorescence waned in Russia, and ways in<br />

which it may evolve to a more sustainable<br />

efflorescence and thus achieving “modern”<br />

economic growth. However, before one<br />

can speak of the Russian experience with<br />

efflorescence, it is first necessary to<br />

understand how efflorescence occurs.<br />

According to Goldstone, efflorescence<br />

tends to occur under the following<br />

conditions:<br />

(1) During periods when<br />

international trade and<br />

sustained contact lead to a<br />

mixing of cultures and ideas;<br />

and (2) in places that are<br />

centers of international trade,<br />

in which people, goods, and<br />

techniques are focused on<br />

meeting multiple commercial<br />

demands. One could add as a<br />

third factor that (3) such<br />

efflorescences also seem<br />

more likely during periods of<br />

reconstruction following a<br />

collapse or massive challenge<br />

or change in government or<br />

society that unleashes new<br />

energies or social groups or<br />

provides integration and<br />

order over larger territories. 5<br />

Conversely, efflorescence is unlikely in<br />

societies isolated from cross-cultural<br />

influences or in societies that depend on a<br />

few commodities, which make the<br />

countries vulnerable to global shifts and<br />

limit their ability to diversify toward<br />

“multiple commercial demands” 6 . It is also<br />

unlikely during periods of unchallenged<br />

political order, where elites reject creative<br />

reconstruction and instead enforce<br />

conformity to existing practices.<br />

Many times in Russia, periods of<br />

oscillating efflorescence were due to<br />

fluctuations in the oil and natural gas<br />

markets. Russia faces a significant threat<br />

from negative impacts on its economy<br />

stemming from overreliance on a small set<br />

of commodities, specifically oil and gas. In<br />

the occurrence of the economic<br />

phenomenon termed “Dutch Disease,” 7<br />

overreliance on natural resources distorts<br />

the economy because the country slackens<br />

its other means of revenue generation (tax,<br />

infrastructure, investment) and depends on<br />

the revenues from a single set of<br />

commodities.<br />

5 Ibid, 31<br />

6 Ibid.<br />

7 The term stems from the 1960s and 1970s, a<br />

period when the Dutch economy became too<br />

specialized in the export of natural resources,<br />

ultimately crowding out other industries.<br />

68 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 68


Structurally, it is difficult to claim<br />

that economic “backwardness,” stemming<br />

from Russia’s authoritative policies and its<br />

integrated economic structure, was the<br />

main cause for Russia’s unsustainable<br />

growth and waning efflorescence. In fact,<br />

after the collapse of the Soviet Union,<br />

some domestic reforms such as liberal<br />

market reform and cultural change from<br />

tacit compliance to glasnost—a period of<br />

free speech and expression—brought on<br />

temporary efflorescence. However,<br />

Russia’s domestic reforms, such as<br />

perestroika under Soviet Union President<br />

Mikhail Gorbachev played a notable role in<br />

creating an entrenched oligarchic<br />

community in Russia, which still holds<br />

significant power and works to reinforce<br />

conformity to a natural resource, their<br />

pecuniary base. 8 As Goldstones makes<br />

clear, elite entrenchment diminishes<br />

efflorescence. These conditions constitute<br />

aspects of Russia’s “peculiar path.”<br />

Efflorescence opens the door to<br />

understanding Russia’s growth trajectory<br />

more effectively, which may have posed<br />

illusive if the country was analyzed under a<br />

strict Schumpeterian or Smithian<br />

framework, or under the belief that<br />

modernization needs to mimic Western<br />

economies. Thus, by separately examining<br />

Russia’s efflorescences after the 1998 and<br />

2008 crisis, we uncover the mechanisms<br />

driving and destroying a sustainable<br />

efflorescence in Russia.<br />

8 Perestroika literally means “restructuring.” It was a<br />

policy implemented to introduce market-like<br />

reforms into the Soviet System. Its most<br />

prototypical reform was privatization with<br />

vouchers. These vouchers are chiefly responsible<br />

for what we now term “Russian oligarchs.”<br />

1998 AND 2008 CRISES<br />

Russia underwent a seven-year<br />

period of efflorescence after the creation of<br />

the Russian Federation in 1991. Faced with<br />

a challenging economic situation, the<br />

economy made incremental movements<br />

toward positive GDP growth from 1991 to<br />

1997. In transitioning from a fiscal deficit<br />

representing -12.6 percent of GDP in 1994<br />

to a fiscal surplus of 1.4 percent of GDP in<br />

1997, Russia’s efflorescence changed the<br />

economic landscape, increasing the quality<br />

of life for its citizens and reconstructing its<br />

position in the global economy. 9 The<br />

growth from 1994 to 1997 relates directly<br />

to factors one and two of Goldstones<br />

causes for efflorescence: increased<br />

international trade, heightened<br />

international connections, and a period of<br />

reconstruction following the collapse the<br />

old regime. Both the World Bank (WB)<br />

and the International Monetary Fund<br />

(IMF) supported the formation of the<br />

Russian Federations, which also helped<br />

attract foreign investment. Moreover, to<br />

address its fiscal deficit, the Russian<br />

government engaged in financial<br />

innovations such as creating Government<br />

Short-Term Commitments (GKO)—shortterm,<br />

zero-coupon Russian government<br />

treasury bills—which provided noninflationary<br />

means toward financing budget<br />

deficits.<br />

Unfortunately, this period of<br />

efflorescence ended abruptly. Unlike the<br />

trends for successful efflorescence that<br />

Goldstone outlines, Russia’s international<br />

trade did not meet enough commercial<br />

demands. The geographical distribution of<br />

Russian foreign trade changed after the<br />

collapse of the Soviet Union. In 1985,<br />

around 55 percent of Soviet exports and<br />

9 Iris van de Wiel, “The Russian Crisis 1998:<br />

Economic Research,” (The Netherlands:<br />

Rabobank, 2013).<br />

69 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 69


imports were within the Eastern Bloc, or<br />

Comecon countries. 10 By 1991, only 23<br />

percent of exports and imports were with<br />

the former Comecon member states.<br />

However, after 1991, trade with advanced<br />

economies such as Europe, Japan, and the<br />

U.S. were growing but not enough to<br />

compensate for the falloff in trade with<br />

past allies. Moreover, oil, natural gas,<br />

metals, and minerals, accounted for 65<br />

percent of total exports in 1993 indicating<br />

that Russia’s export sector was nascent. 11<br />

Additionally, the change in the government<br />

after the collapse of the Soviet Union<br />

brought about new institutional problems,<br />

namely corruption. The broader fragility of<br />

Russia’s economy would become more<br />

apparent over time.<br />

Owing to burgeoning global<br />

financial interconnections, the Asian Crisis<br />

of 1997, which started with the collapse of<br />

the Thai baht currency in July, kick-started<br />

a global economic crisis. 12 Russia felt the<br />

reverberations of the Asian Crisis as<br />

investor speculation against the Russian<br />

ruble caused a devaluation of the currency.<br />

Between defending their currency by<br />

spending almost USD 6 billion of foreign<br />

exchange reserves and the tumble in world<br />

commodity prices, Russia experienced its<br />

most severe crisis in August of 1998. 13<br />

Eventually, defending the currency failed<br />

and the ruble devalued. Russia defaulted on<br />

10 The Comecon countries are: Soviet Union,<br />

Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, the German<br />

Democratic Republic (East Germany), Hungary,<br />

Romania, Poland, Cuba, the Mongolian People's<br />

Republic (Mongolia), and Vietnam.<br />

11 Glenn E. Curtis, “Foreign Economic Relations”<br />

in Russia: A Country Study ed., (Washington: GPO<br />

for the Library of Congress, 1996).<br />

12 This was purportedly due in large to massive<br />

currency speculation by New York hedge fund<br />

manager George Soros, after he shorted the<br />

currency that year.<br />

13 “National Wealth Fund Statistics,” Russian<br />

National Wealth Fund.<br />

http://old.minfin.ru/en/reservefund/index.php<br />

its GKOs and coupon-bearing Federal<br />

Loan Bonds (OFZ), and announced a 90-<br />

day moratorium on payments to foreign<br />

creditors by commercial banks: effectively,<br />

a sovereign default. 14<br />

Adding to the destruction, Russia’s<br />

dependency on world energy prices<br />

exacerbated the damage. From 1991 to<br />

1997, rising oil and energy prices led to<br />

Russia’s efflorescence. However, in the<br />

wake of the Asian crisis, the natural<br />

commodities market plummeted with<br />

energy prices, sliding from 1997 onwards,<br />

further burdening Russia’s economy. The<br />

torrents of economic mayhem affected<br />

Russia throughout 1998 and by the<br />

beginning of 1999, actual GDP, and GDP<br />

growth were both below their pre-1996<br />

levels.<br />

Luckily, by the late-1990s investor<br />

sentiment started to relax, capital flight<br />

slowed and world commodity prices<br />

bounced back. The price of crude oil,<br />

which played a big role in pulling the<br />

Russian economy out of efflorescence<br />

between 1998 and 1999, conversely stoked<br />

efflorescence after 1999. The price rose to<br />

an average $10 USD per barrel higher than<br />

the previous 5 years. The commodity<br />

boom bolstered the rate at which the<br />

Russian economy was able to recover from<br />

the 1998 crisis. During the third quarter of<br />

1999, Russia’s annual GDP grew by 11.5<br />

percent and then by 12.1 percent in the<br />

fourth quarter of 1999.<br />

If the 1998 crisis was the first and<br />

only crisis to have impacted Russia, foreign<br />

analysts and Russians alike would have<br />

easily overlooked the apparent signs of a<br />

fragile economy. Emphasis would have<br />

been placed on Russia’s rapid recovery, and<br />

its high dependency on oil and energy<br />

would have been praised as a successful<br />

14 Wiel, “The Russian Crisis 1998.”<br />

70 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 70


hedge. Analysts could have claim that it is<br />

inevitable for a nascent market economy<br />

recovering from the collapse of a<br />

communist society to face initial hardship.<br />

However, Russia’s deep structural<br />

economic weaknesses were revealed by<br />

crisis in 2008. In 2009, Russian Specialist,<br />

Jeffery Mankoff, criticized Russia’s internal<br />

economic mechanics that persisted since<br />

the 1998 crisis:<br />

[A] foreign policy based on<br />

the revenues from highenergy<br />

prices is necessarily<br />

hostage to fluctuations in the<br />

global energy market, as<br />

indeed it was during the<br />

Soviet Union’s economic<br />

boom of the 1970s and the<br />

subsequent bust of the 1980s.<br />

Moreover, Russia’s economy<br />

is still inflexible and<br />

uncompetitive. 15<br />

The 2008 crisis proved that future<br />

efflorescence in Russia would be<br />

unsustainable if the country saw no<br />

structural changes. The Russian economy<br />

could not sustain growth because it<br />

suffered from internal weaknesses and an<br />

over-reliance on one commodity.<br />

However, structural reform can be a very<br />

tough pill to swallow, especially if structural<br />

inefficiency allowed for quick recoveries<br />

from two financial crises.<br />

Russia may have suffered the most<br />

of all the BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India, and<br />

China) countries at the onset of the<br />

financial crisis, but Russia grew faster<br />

before the crisis, and its recovery was<br />

quicker thanks to its oil dependency. As<br />

Clifford Gaddy and Barry Ickes succinctly<br />

exemplify:<br />

15 Jeffrey Mankoff, Russian Foreign Policy: The Return<br />

of Great Power Politics. (USA: Rowman & Littlefield,<br />

2009), 48.<br />

This is worth<br />

repeating…Russia is still<br />

significantly richer in 2010<br />

than it would have been had<br />

it grown at a rate as fast as<br />

the next-fastest BRIC<br />

[country] since 1999. Russia<br />

clearly would not have gained<br />

from having “diversified”<br />

away from energy in 1999. 16<br />

Russia’s growth was in large part due to its<br />

massive reserve fund, and the revenues that<br />

it had built through natural resource sales.<br />

The reserve fund, a product of the<br />

stabilization fund put in place after the<br />

1998 crisis, gave Russia access to foreign<br />

currency that it could spend to fight off<br />

capital flight and bolster the depreciating<br />

currency.<br />

Unlike other countries that were<br />

forced to invoke significant monetary<br />

policy mechanisms which lead to inflation<br />

and devalued currencies, Russia could<br />

offset most of the pain by drawing upon its<br />

reserves fund. This allowed the country to<br />

curtail unnecessary monetary policy, which<br />

could prove problematic after external<br />

shocks subside and business-as-usual<br />

returns. During the financial crisis, Russia’s<br />

increase in expenditures outpaced the<br />

revenues raised by the government, leading<br />

to a budget deficit by 2009. Additionally,<br />

Russia spent 22 percent of its total<br />

reserves, or USD $1.3 billion from 2008 to<br />

2009. This illustrates that in order to<br />

counteract the 2008 crisis, Russia spent an<br />

excessive amount of its reserves and<br />

diminished its fiscal balance.<br />

To recover, four years of building a<br />

healthy fiscal balance disappeared, and a<br />

year worth of reserves evaporated. The<br />

16 Clifford G. Gaddy and Barry W. Ickes. “Russia<br />

After The Global Financial Crisis.” Eurasian<br />

Geography and Economics 51, no.3 (2010), 291.<br />

71 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 71


sheer amount spent to offset the crisis is a<br />

cause for concern. Without oil revenues<br />

replenishing its reserves, Russia could not<br />

justify spending such large sums.<br />

Moreover, during the second half of 2008,<br />

Russia’s stock market had shed more than<br />

90 percent of its value. By 2009, after such<br />

large fiscal injections consumer spending<br />

still shrank by 7.9 percent, indicating that<br />

Russian’s were worried about the future of<br />

their economy. 17 For the first time since<br />

1999, Russia again ran a budget deficit.<br />

In light of this, we see that the<br />

reserves built via the high dependency on<br />

oil only points to a more integral flaw. The<br />

effects of the 2008 crisis highlighted<br />

Russia’s Dutch disease, and its vulnerability<br />

to the sways of the international<br />

environment. Because oil revenues are<br />

accumulated through export sales, Russia’s<br />

government budget depends on oil prices,<br />

and international demand/supply<br />

dynamics. Ultimately, Russia’s dependency<br />

on oil helped to revive the economy from a<br />

crisis, but it also jeopardized it when those<br />

commodity prices tumbled. Gaddy and<br />

Ickes point out this observation as well<br />

when he states:<br />

First, the crisis has reminded<br />

us of how thoroughly<br />

dependent Russia is on oil<br />

and gas. Looking at the<br />

period before the crisis,<br />

during the crisis, and now in<br />

the rebound, the picture is<br />

unambiguous. Very few<br />

important developments,<br />

positive or negative, cannot<br />

be traced back to fluctuations<br />

in the volume of wealth—the<br />

rents—that accrue to Russia<br />

from these resources.<br />

(Resource) addiction’s most<br />

pernicious feature is that it is<br />

self-reinforcing, which means<br />

that it continually deepens<br />

and reproduces<br />

backwardness and<br />

inefficiency in the Russian<br />

economy. 18<br />

Ultimately, both crises of 1998 and 2008<br />

draw out the pertinence in understanding<br />

how efflorescence occurred in Russian.<br />

After the 1990 collapse of the Soviet<br />

Union, Russia experienced a brief<br />

efflorescence that was stumped because its<br />

export was still immature. After the 1998<br />

crisis, Russia’s dependence on oil allowed<br />

for another efflorescence, but overreliance<br />

on oil and gas revenues limited its<br />

expansion along multiple economic<br />

indicators, ultimately creating a short-term<br />

efflorescence, restricting it in the long run.<br />

Nevertheless, disagreement still<br />

exists on whether the 1998 and 2008 crises<br />

illustrate Russia’s dependency on a few<br />

commodities. Many of the country’s<br />

analysts and economists question whether<br />

Russia, in fact, suffers from “Dutch<br />

disease.” To find answers they often<br />

evaluate the future of Russia’s natural<br />

resource sector to consider its ability to rely<br />

on oil and gas exports and what<br />

relationship that has on Russia’s willingness<br />

to diversify its economy.<br />

OIL AND ENERGY<br />

If one does not look deeply into<br />

the problem, Russia’s dependency on its<br />

natural resources may appear positive<br />

rather than negative. It may be true that the<br />

Reserves Fund and National Wealth Fund<br />

have had beneficial impacts on Russia’s<br />

17 Mankoff, Russian Foreign Policy: The Return of Great<br />

Power Politics.<br />

18 Gaddy and Ickes. “Russia After The Global<br />

Financial Crisis,” 282.<br />

72 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 72


economy. However, a closer look at the<br />

long-term perspective exposes the negative<br />

effects of overreliance on such funds.<br />

Russia’s exports in the oil and gas sector<br />

accounts to 70 percent of its exports or 28<br />

percent of its GDP. To place that in<br />

context, India’s oil sector, for example, is<br />

only 18 percent of all exports.<br />

Comparatively, for the U.S., capital goods,<br />

industrial goods, and consumer goods<br />

together make up 65 percent of all<br />

exports. 19 Because Russia can generate<br />

revenue and saving from oil and gas sales,<br />

it is dis-incentivized to innovate new<br />

avenues of wealth creation.<br />

This level of dependency has<br />

proven to be problematic before. Firstly,<br />

Russia’s economic growth closely tracks<br />

worldwide oil demand and price. Secondly,<br />

when oil price is stable but other exports<br />

and sources of revenue are not developed,<br />

the economy approaches decline. In 2012,<br />

Russia’s economic growth was 3.4 percent,<br />

the lowest level since 1990 minus the<br />

global recession of 2008-2009. This was<br />

primarily because the volume of Russia’s<br />

exports other than oil and gas had declined<br />

amid worldwide recessions. 20<br />

High correlations between crude oil<br />

prices and Russian trade and exports<br />

exemplify structural risk. For example,<br />

trade mainly mirrored the movements of<br />

Urals oil prices in 2011 and 2012 rising to<br />

$400 million in 2011 when oil prices<br />

reached $120, and falling together by the<br />

middle of 2012 when oil sank below<br />

$100. 21 Additionally, the trend in export<br />

follows that of global oil demand. The<br />

figures illustrate Neil Rubinstein’s claim<br />

that “when oil prices have been high,<br />

Russia has grown its economy and<br />

balanced its budget; when they have been<br />

low, growth has reversed, and deficits have<br />

returned.” 22<br />

Furthermore, in 2003, 40 percent<br />

of Russia’s revenues were based on oil and<br />

gas taxes. That number increased by 8<br />

percent through 2010. 23 Thus, with this<br />

trend we see that when demand for oil<br />

decreases, revenues also decrease because<br />

fewer taxes are collected Additionally, the<br />

reliance on oil has linked Russia to the<br />

global world more integrally in many ways.<br />

As presented, both crises of 1998 and 2008<br />

were based on external tremors. More<br />

threats from external sources may lie<br />

ahead. By investing in a diversified<br />

economy, Russia can decouple its growth<br />

from natural resource rents, allowing it to<br />

have sectors of its economy insulated from<br />

external shocks.<br />

Though Russia’s dependency on oil<br />

does not pose immediate threat to its<br />

economy, a series of future problems will<br />

affect its growth in the long term. Crude oil<br />

prices are on a slow decline in recent years.<br />

Decreasing oil and gas demand in Europe,<br />

Russia’s number one importer of oil and<br />

gas, is also a cause for concern. Fiscal and<br />

monetary instability in Europe led to an<br />

economic slowdown for Russia in the<br />

second half of 2012. Additionally, Europe<br />

is continuously looking for new sources of<br />

energy to deter its reliance on Russian oil<br />

and gas. In response, Russia has turned to<br />

strategic relations with China. The growing<br />

population and expanding economy of<br />

China has prompted the need for higher<br />

19 Securing America’s Future Energy (SAFE) and<br />

Roubini Global Economics, “Oil Security Index,”<br />

www.OilSecurityIndex.org, October 2013.<br />

20 The National Institute for Defense Studies, “East<br />

Asian Strategic Review” (Tokyo, The Japan Times,<br />

Ltd., 2013), 254.<br />

21 Ibid.<br />

22 Neil Robinson, ed., “Russia's Potential Role in<br />

the World Oil System” in Political Economy of Russia<br />

(USA: Rowman & Littlefield, 2012), 156.<br />

23 Robertson and Graeme, “Russian Protesters: Not<br />

Optimistic But Here to Stay,” Russian Analytical<br />

Digest, 20, no.115 (2012).<br />

73 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 73


natural resource consumption. However,<br />

between China’s slowing economy and its<br />

own endeavors for acquiring natural<br />

resources abroad, the short-term likelihood<br />

of China bringing a big boost to the<br />

Russian economy is low.<br />

At the writing of this report, based<br />

on the rising stockpiles of crude oil in the<br />

U.S. and higher-than-expected production<br />

of oil in Libya, crude oil prices have been<br />

on a continuous decline since November<br />

2013. 24 This decline in oil prices mirrors a<br />

stagnating Russian economy. Based on<br />

Roubini Global Economics’ projections,<br />

Russia’s GDP growth for 2014 will be as<br />

low as 2 percent and its current growth is<br />

about 1.4 percent. 25 In the past, Russia has<br />

been consistently lucky with the strength of<br />

oil prices. However, in this case, strength<br />

can be equivalent to overreliance. It is<br />

important not to ignore how Russia’s<br />

efflorescences have emerged cyclically due<br />

to changes in the oil price. It is<br />

understandably beneficial to recover<br />

quickly from a crisis, but it is just as bad to<br />

have a country’s growth stripped from it<br />

because of resource prices. If Russia is to<br />

aim for sustained economic growth and<br />

efflorescence that maintains stride long<br />

enough to become a modernizing<br />

economy, diversification is needed. The<br />

question is, as asked in Thane Gustafson’s<br />

book, Wheel of Fortune: The battle for power and<br />

oil in Russia, is Russia “a classic petro-state,”<br />

with its “hypertrophied hydrocarbon<br />

industries inflicting a ‘resource curse’ on<br />

non-energy industries suffering from<br />

Dutch disease.” 26 The answer to such a<br />

24 ICN.com, “Oil Set For First Three-Week Slide In<br />

2013: Commodity Market Commentaries,”<br />

Oilngold.com, April 19, 2013.<br />

25 “Russia Country Analysis,” Roubini Global<br />

Economics. Accessed on December 2013,<br />

https://www.roubini.com.<br />

26 Thane, Gustafson, Wheel of Fortune: The Battle for<br />

Oil and Power in Russia, (USA: Harvard University Press,<br />

2012).<br />

question continues to be elusive because of<br />

the recent changes in Russia’s economic<br />

growth plan.<br />

Currently, Russia is investing in<br />

infrastructure, using the National Wealth<br />

Fund as a source of revenue. Here it is<br />

important to note the change in strategy.<br />

Instead of using those reserves to avoid<br />

diversified investment, Russia appears to<br />

be changing its approach. Additionally,<br />

Russia is attempting to provide incentives<br />

for companies to explore the East Siberian<br />

and Far East Greenfields as well as the<br />

offshore arctic Bluefield for untapped oil<br />

reserves where oil is harder to access but of<br />

higher quality. 27 Here we see a positive<br />

relationship with its oil rents whereby<br />

Russia rolls over surplus into productive<br />

investments. Nonetheless, this trend is<br />

nascent and it cannot be guaranteed to<br />

persist. Moreover, oil is only one particular<br />

bottleneck Russia may be facing in regards<br />

to maintaining efflorescence.<br />

Goldstone addresses that selfsustaining<br />

growth is not dependent on a<br />

“cluster of innovations,” or by alleviating a<br />

particular bottleneck, “rather it is a matter<br />

of developing a particular approach to<br />

production and technological innovations.”<br />

Additionally, he claims, “it is long overdue<br />

to incorporate changes in social<br />

attitudes…into our conceptions of what<br />

underlay the sudden onset of selfsustaining<br />

and accelerating growth.” 28 In<br />

accord with his statement, I turn to the<br />

regime of Vladimir Putin and to the<br />

developments in Russia’s civil society after<br />

the 2011 protests.<br />

27 Ibid.<br />

28 Goldstone, “Efflorescences and Economic<br />

Growth in World History: Rethinking The “Rise Of<br />

The West” and The Industrial Revolution,” 31.<br />

74 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 74


POST-PROTEST AND PUTIN’S<br />

RUSSIA<br />

In his theory of efflorescence,<br />

Goldstone points out that efflorescences<br />

are usually accompanied by massive<br />

challenges against the social order or<br />

challenges against governments. Thus, the<br />

social fabric of a country is as important to<br />

efflorescence as any other indicator. In this<br />

regard, Russia has a recent trend worth<br />

noting. By late 2011, civil society started to<br />

visibly stir in Russia. Protests began to pop<br />

up in Moscow and other major Russian<br />

cities. Many Russian specialists watched<br />

attentively as protesters amassed, calling<br />

for a structural change and the stepping<br />

down of President Putin. In December,<br />

Putin reinforced the idea of a tandem<br />

leadership between himself and then<br />

President Dmitry Medvedev—announcing<br />

that he would be swapping positions with<br />

Medvedev for Presidency over Vice-<br />

Presidency. Not long after this<br />

announcement, discontented protestors<br />

took to the street to express their views on<br />

domestic corruption. Chants for “Rossiya<br />

bez Putina - Russia, without Putin,” could<br />

be heard en masse roving down the busy<br />

streets of Moscow. Financial instability<br />

amongst the population has caused some<br />

citizens to worry about the conditions of<br />

their country. Moreover, due of the rising<br />

middle class, the amount of educated<br />

civilians who are aware of corruption rose.<br />

By December 2011, it became apparent<br />

that the changing dynamics of Russia’s civil<br />

society would pose significant challenges to<br />

the government. These events will have<br />

much to do with the potential durability of<br />

efflorescence in Russia post the 2008 crisis.<br />

It is important to place these<br />

challenges amidst the phenomenon of<br />

creative destruction. This concept, as<br />

previously referenced, pertains to the<br />

elimination of older technologies as more<br />

efficient alternatives are developed. As<br />

society unleashes new energies that aim to<br />

provide a new structure more capable of<br />

sustaining efflorescence, older structures<br />

are challenged and dissolved. However,<br />

Goldstone warns that many times a<br />

country falls into Caldwell’s law, which<br />

states that when new productive practices<br />

or forces cause growth in an economy, they<br />

will also create interest groups vested by<br />

the political and social elite. These interest<br />

groups constrict future creative destruction<br />

because they desire to reap the benefits<br />

from the monopolies they have acquired.<br />

Thus, such groups generate stagnation, and<br />

decline of efflorescence. For Russia,<br />

Caldwell’s law depicts the country’s schism<br />

between its citizenry—Oligarchy vs. the<br />

budding middle class. Goldstone explains<br />

that when this occurs, “only a major social<br />

or political upheaval is then likely to create<br />

new opportunities for major episodes of<br />

growth.” 29 Many indeed thought this<br />

particular upheaval was occurring in Russia<br />

during 2011. Graeme Robertson stated,<br />

“Russia had woken up.” 30 His words were<br />

mirrored by a series of academics and<br />

analysts who saw 2011 as the time for civil<br />

society in Russia to start its engine toward<br />

Russia 2.0. Unfortunately, such changes are<br />

much harder to initiate than initially<br />

thought.<br />

In 2012, Putin regained his<br />

presidency. A vast amount of the<br />

protestors had been arrested before and<br />

after the State Duma elections and Putin’s<br />

inauguration. By June 2012, legislation was<br />

passed to sharply raise the fines imposed<br />

for engaging in unauthorized<br />

demonstrations, and in October Russia’s<br />

criminal code was amended to classify such<br />

29 Ibid.<br />

30 Graeme Robertson, “Russian Protesters: Not<br />

Optimistic But Here to Stay.” Russian Analytical<br />

Digest 20, no.115 (2012).<br />

75 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 75


activities as acts of treason. 31 As it became<br />

more difficult for massive social uprising to<br />

form, confidence in reforms diminished.<br />

Cases such as the “Pussy Riot” arrests have<br />

frightened many youths who do not want<br />

to be jailed. Harsh fines have made<br />

protesting a sport for the wealthy.<br />

Evghenia Sleptsova, a Russian<br />

economic analyst writing on Russian<br />

Growth, states, as well as many others, that<br />

“Putin’s model of governance, whereby the<br />

population gives up part of democracy in<br />

return for economic stability, [is] adding to<br />

the political risks.” 32 In order to enjoy the<br />

fruits of economic growth, people are<br />

coerced to deal with the system. This<br />

method appears counter intuitive and<br />

ineffective in light of Goldstone’s<br />

efflorescence theory. Goldstone warns<br />

against conforming to existing practices<br />

enforced by elite command. By siding with<br />

the status quo, Russia begs for its own<br />

stagnation. Indeed, such stagnation has<br />

already arrived.<br />

The government acknowledged its<br />

own sluggishness during fiscal year 2013,<br />

and has abandoned its hopes of 4 percent<br />

GDP growth, forecasting downward to 2.5<br />

percent. 33 Thus, Robertson’s statement is<br />

brought back in the form of a question: will<br />

Russia wake up? Analyst Sleptsova stated<br />

that:<br />

By slashing the long-term growth<br />

forecast the government effectively<br />

admits that growth will continue to<br />

track the stagnant oil prices and<br />

demand, and does not expect any<br />

significant economic break-through<br />

or diversification of the economy.<br />

31 The National Institute for Defense Studies, “East<br />

Asian Strategic Review 2013.”<br />

32 Evghenia Sleptsova, “Russian Growth: Slowing<br />

Down and Not Much Acceleration in Sight.”<br />

Roubini Global Economics.com, November 11, 2013.<br />

33 Ibid.<br />

Therefore, as stagnant hydrocarbon<br />

revenues and restrictive fiscal<br />

policy will constrain public<br />

investment, and private sector<br />

investment will continue to be<br />

suppressed by weak rule of law and<br />

corruption, investment will serve as<br />

a drag on growth. 34<br />

It must be said, however, that it is unfair to<br />

tell this tale as if the Russian government is<br />

not ostensibly aiming to suppress<br />

stagnation-causing policies. Putin has<br />

implemented a series of small fixes, which<br />

have boosted Russia’s 2013 World Bank<br />

rating up 20 points from 112 th to 92 nd ,<br />

signifying that Russia is taking steps toward<br />

improving its business climate. Moreover,<br />

Putin ambitiously states that he wants that<br />

ranking to rise to 20 th place by 2018.<br />

Additionally, Russia plans to spend 13.6<br />

billion rubles on public infrastructure.<br />

However, many see these changes as only<br />

minimal—maintaining stagnation, but not<br />

spurring efflorescence. Specialists at The<br />

Economist are also skeptical. They state that<br />

“profound reforms” will now be needed.<br />

Mirroring the statement of Sleptsova, they<br />

call particularly for reforms to the courts,<br />

legal system, judiciary system, and law<br />

enforcement. 35 With an anachronistic<br />

examination of economic growth, it may<br />

seem that such changes will only stem from<br />

Schumpeterian growth and the adaptation<br />

of liberal democratic reforms. However,<br />

this author cautions against overt cynicism<br />

and instead encourages moderated caution<br />

in regards to the Russian government’s<br />

ability to implement the needed reforms.<br />

Ultimately, the question is, how<br />

threatened is the Russian system by its<br />

inability to allow creative destruction to run<br />

34 Ibid.<br />

35 “The S word; Russia's economy,” The Economist,<br />

November 9, 2013.<br />

76 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 76


its course? Currently, Russia is taking steps<br />

that prove it can liberate itself from an<br />

overreaching government and a corrupt<br />

oligarchic system. One interesting<br />

movement in this direction has been the<br />

reappointment of Alexey Kudrin, former<br />

liberal Finance Minister from 2001. Putin<br />

appointed Kudrin to the Presidium of the<br />

Economic Council on October 31 2013. In<br />

2012, Silvana Malle, former head of the<br />

Non-Member Economies Division at the<br />

OECD Economics Department stated,<br />

“Alexey Kudrin have been pointed out as<br />

possible leaders of alternative parties” 36<br />

During the 2008 economic crisis, Kudrin<br />

played a key role in steering the country<br />

through the global financial crisis, famously<br />

quitting his position as Russia’s military<br />

budget ballooned against his will.<br />

Furthermore, developments such as the<br />

government voting to allow free mayoral<br />

elections in Russia’s largest cities, illustrate<br />

that creative destruction can be<br />

implemented from the top down. 37<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

By examining Russia under the lens<br />

of Goldstone’s historical economic<br />

efflorescence, a less ambiguous and<br />

evolving picture of Russia’s current<br />

situation surfaces. Over the years, Russia<br />

has established a consistent reliance on its<br />

key resources and over-utilization of<br />

political power to ride out its crises. These<br />

tactics were not predominantly all bad<br />

choices. They have allowed Russia to grow<br />

on many occasions. However, the bigger<br />

picture is also visible. The purpose of<br />

36 Silvana Malle, "The Policy Challenges of Russia's<br />

Post-Crisis Economy," Post-Soviet Affairs 28, no.1,<br />

(2012), 82.<br />

37 Yulia Latynina, “How Yevgeny Roizman Became<br />

Mayor,” (The Moscow Times, September 18, 2013).<br />

http://www.themoscowtimes.com/opinion/article<br />

/how-yevgeny-roizman-becamemayor/486235.html.<br />

efflorescence is to foster sustained<br />

economic growth and to evolve into a<br />

flourishing and modernizing economy. It is<br />

during this final transition that Russia's<br />

methods lose their appeal. High reliance on<br />

oil encourages resource addiction, allowing<br />

Russia to finance many of its problems and<br />

recover quickly from shocks. However,<br />

such reliance also causes Russia to<br />

strengthen only a few commodities sectors<br />

instead of diversifying. In an evolving<br />

world, such tactics are risky. Oil may not<br />

disappear, but developed countries<br />

throughout the world are investing in new<br />

technologies. Europe is pedantically<br />

watching its reliance on Russia, and China<br />

is voraciously scouring the globe for its<br />

own means to development. However, in<br />

contrast, this essay has also illustrated<br />

aspects that may lead to sustained<br />

efflorescence in Russia.<br />

In recent years, a tendency for the<br />

government and private corporations to<br />

turn to various investments, such as their<br />

military modernizations, investments in<br />

infrastructure, and the expansion of oil<br />

exploration technologies may enable Russia<br />

to overcome some of its bottlenecks. In<br />

Russia, as with all nations, it is important to<br />

heed Goldstone’s insight: every economy<br />

overcame economic stagnation in a way<br />

specific to its own resources and<br />

conditions. The future investments Russia<br />

plans to make, and the investments it has<br />

already made, point to a new and<br />

interesting occurrence of top-down<br />

reforms. This method is yet to be fully<br />

tested; however, it does not automatically<br />

call for skepticism.<br />

Russia’s future falls heavily on three<br />

developments: First, Russia needs to<br />

follows its proposed projects to limit its<br />

resource dependency. Second, Russia must<br />

address its legal system to stave off<br />

corruption, and implement reforms that<br />

may lead to creative destruction. Finally, as<br />

77 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 77


the social attitudes, and the civil conditions<br />

in Russia evolve we can heed Goldstone’s<br />

claim:<br />

It just so happened that in the<br />

background of …efflorescences –<br />

that of eighteenth-century<br />

England—there lurked a particular<br />

cultural content … that combined<br />

with that otherwise normal<br />

efflorescence to create wholly novel<br />

breakthroughs… 38 (Emphasis<br />

added.)<br />

Cultural content was the creation of a<br />

“scientific culture” in England, which led a<br />

rich culture in experimentation eventually<br />

leading to the invention of the steam<br />

engine. This cultural content will always be<br />

different and specific to a country. For<br />

Russia, a cultural content may be budding<br />

in its civil society’s changing temperament.<br />

Larger swaths of Russian citizens now<br />

express new desires and demands; they<br />

want a new way to structure their lives<br />

based on less corruption, more freedom to<br />

protest, advanced avenues for<br />

entrepreneurship by shrinking oligarchic<br />

monopolies, and enhanced access to the<br />

global economy which brings with it a vast<br />

array of goods. It is possible that among<br />

those many demands lay the fodder for<br />

structural change in Russia.<br />

Regrettably, over time, the ability of<br />

Russia’s civilians to cause upheavals against<br />

the system seem to be combatted by strict<br />

laws and centralized power. As the world<br />

around Putin gives birth to more protests<br />

and rebellions, he appears to become more<br />

cautious of domestic ruckus. Depending<br />

on the tide of civil society, Russia could be<br />

compelled to meet the demands of its<br />

middle class. Those citizens, who want<br />

more than abstract GDP growth, will<br />

demand for the diversification of their<br />

economy. As civil unrest strains the powersharing<br />

structure between the government<br />

and the oligarchs it is undeniably important<br />

when considering Russia’s ability to break<br />

from its “otherwise normal” oscillations<br />

between efflorescence and stagnation, to<br />

look for the creation of a “cultural<br />

content.” Such content will define Russian<br />

society in a way best suited for advanced<br />

growth. This will be both a structural<br />

change and consequently, a change in the<br />

collective mentality.<br />

As Russia continues its struggle to<br />

sustain efflorescence, analysts should<br />

consider a Russia-specific phenomenon as<br />

the solution. It is only in this way that<br />

observers will understand more holistically<br />

the potential for sustained, and enduring<br />

efflorescence in Russia.<br />

JOEL ALEXANDER graduated with a bachelor's<br />

degree in Political Science from Columbia<br />

University, and is currently pursuing a master's<br />

degree in Global Affairs at New York University’s<br />

Center for Global Affairs in the International<br />

Business and Economics concentration. He is<br />

currently the Vice President for the Society of<br />

International Business and Economics at NYU.<br />

38 Goldstone, Jack A, “Efflorescences and<br />

Economic Growth in World History: Rethinking<br />

The “Rise Of The West” and The Industrial<br />

Revolution,” 376.<br />

78 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 78


Iraq: State Or National<br />

Collapse?<br />

Paul Mutter<br />

I<br />

I<br />

n the twentieth and twenty-first centuries,<br />

Iraq has lacked a strong sense of<br />

nationhood and a stable civil society. In<br />

their place rose a “fierce state” that prioritized<br />

the maintenance of security services to uphold<br />

the leaders’ power and an “uncivil society” of<br />

the country’s ruling class who existed apart<br />

from the lumpen masses but were barred<br />

from associating and organizing freely.<br />

Following U.S. occupation in 2003, Iraq’s<br />

“fierce state” and “uncivil society” unraveled<br />

quite rapidly. In the absence of a state for all<br />

its citizens, or more inclusive civil society<br />

institutions, sectarianism became the primary<br />

mode of political association. It is in sectarian<br />

terms that disputes are still framed, and armed<br />

camps organized. The question is, why have<br />

state building efforts failed across the<br />

spectrum in Iraq: is it because of the<br />

authoritarian state’s inherent weakness there,<br />

or because the depths of Iraqi sectarianism<br />

defy attempts to forge a common<br />

nationalism?<br />

The underlying problem, in fact, lies in<br />

the structural weaknesses of the Iraqi state.<br />

Iraq was and is a “fierce state,” but not a<br />

strong one, and this has been the case since its<br />

establishment as a nominally independent<br />

country in 1932. The fundamental weaknesses<br />

predate the U.S. occupation, which merely<br />

exposed them for the international stage. A<br />

“fierce state” seeks to control all aspects of its<br />

peoples’ lives to prevent them from acting on<br />

their rights as citizens. 1 And Iraqi uncivil<br />

1 M. E. Bouillon, “Iraq’s State-Building Enterprise:<br />

State Fragility, State Failure and a New Social<br />

Contract,” International Journal of Contemporary Iraqi<br />

Studies 6, no. 3 (2012): 286, accessed May 5, 2014.<br />

http://ezproxy.library.nyu.edu:15301/eds/pdfviewer/p<br />

society—which consisted of state-mandated<br />

membership for the ruling class in party<br />

organizations—was still basically tribal (as<br />

were most illegal associations outside of<br />

official circles). The Americans’ forced<br />

removal of this type of uncivil society in 2003<br />

saw a proliferation of multiple uncivil societies<br />

organized along ethnosectarian lines. 2<br />

Whether ex-Baathists, Shia militias, the<br />

Kurdish Regional Government, the U.S.- and<br />

Iran-backed federal government, or Sunni<br />

tribal gatherings, the rush to compete in this<br />

new order resulted in massive insecurity and<br />

violence. Sectarian rhetoric often served as<br />

cover for pursuing nakedly materialistic goals<br />

and vendettas. Iraq established a Shiadominated<br />

federal system, but the limited<br />

rights this system observes with respect to<br />

non-Shia means that Iraq will continue to be<br />

wracked by multiple insurgencies. Even now,<br />

the most forceful opponents of the<br />

government are ex-Baathists and Sunni tribes<br />

who see the naked sectarianism of al Qaeda in<br />

Iraq (now reorganized as the “Islamic State of<br />

Iraq and the Levant”) as a vehicle to advance<br />

their interests.<br />

THE NATURE OF “STATE”<br />

Why does the prewar condition of the<br />

Iraqi state matter? As M. E. Bouillon has<br />

noted, after the 1920s, “the state [in Arab<br />

countries] evolved from coveted prize and<br />

target of societal competition to instrument in<br />

the hands of those who had managed to<br />

capture it.” 3 This is what is meant by the<br />

fierce state in the literature. But “fierce” does<br />

not necessarily refer to a strong and stable<br />

dfviewer?sid=012545a9-6521-4dc9-915aa3e4383c5b05%40sessionmgr111&vid=8&hid=104.<br />

2 Phil Williams, “Criminals, Militias, and Insurgents:<br />

Organized Crime in Iraq,” Strategic Studies Institute<br />

(2009): xiii, accessed May 5, 2014.<br />

http://www.strategicstudiesinstitute.army.mil/pdffiles/<br />

pub930.pdf.<br />

3 Bouillon, “Iraq’s State-Building Enterprise,” 283.<br />

79 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 79


state. The fierceness of the state lies in its<br />

need to enforce its rule through violence and<br />

control the distribution of resources to<br />

concentrate (rather than dilute) power in the<br />

hands of a ruling coalition. What happened<br />

after 2003 was not a reverse of the process<br />

that Bouillon saw occurring between the<br />

1920s and the 1960s (when Iraqi Baathists<br />

seized power) but a revival across multiple<br />

coalitions. The paramount challenge for<br />

nation building in Iraq is less a matter of<br />

creating a coherent nationalism for all people<br />

within the border, than creating a state<br />

structure and rule of law within it. Francis<br />

Fukuyama's point that "reconstruction is<br />

possible when the underlying political and<br />

social infrastructure has survived conflict or<br />

crisis" is applicable here because in questions<br />

of building a nation, reconstruction is only<br />

possible if the machinery of state has survived<br />

intact. 4 State structure is a prerequisite to a<br />

successful nation. 5<br />

In Iraq, the rapidity and scale of "de-<br />

Baathification" meant that this premise was<br />

completely undone. 6 Iraqi functionaries forced<br />

out by the U.S. occupation authorities became<br />

rejectionists quite rapidly, aided by access to a<br />

cornucopia of arms caches and a lack of<br />

American troops to put out all the fires they<br />

set. The resulting sectarian conflicts in Iraq<br />

show, as Hawzhin Azeez suggests, “an<br />

attempt to forge their own sense of social<br />

consensus” but this presumes that an Iraq<br />

where the Sunni-Shia divide is still so raw is<br />

one that can actually agree on state structures. 7<br />

The question of “the nation” cannot be<br />

4 Francis Fukuyama, Nation-Building: Beyond Iraq and<br />

Afghanistan, (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University<br />

Press, 2010), Kindle locations 146-147.<br />

5 Ibid., Kindle locations 3916-3918.<br />

6 RAND. “Chapter Ten: Iraq.” In America’s Role in<br />

Nation-Building: From Germany to Iraq. Eds. Dobbins,<br />

James et al. (Santa Monica: RAND, 2003), 166.<br />

7 Hawzhin Azeez, “Reconstructing Iraq: Iraq Statebuilding,<br />

Nation-building, and Violence,” Nebula 7, no.<br />

4 (2010): 80, accessed on May 5, 2014.<br />

http://nobleworld.biz/images/Azeez.pdf.<br />

decided without prior acceptance of powersharing<br />

norms short of internecine warfare.<br />

With several of the country’s major cities still<br />

under the control of the so-called Islamic<br />

State and much of the Kurdish north acting<br />

independent of Baghdad, such norms remain<br />

an illusion. 8 True, even with an extensive<br />

welfare state and security apparatus in place,<br />

the state was weak in Iraq because of the<br />

Baathist’s long rule: one elite group captured<br />

the state, refusing to countenance any other<br />

kind of arrangement or power-sharing<br />

structure that would diminish its powers. 9<br />

This is what made Iraq’s top 1-10% of<br />

citizens—the people who ran the various<br />

ministries and security services—an uncivil<br />

society. They were committed to an order that<br />

barred them and the rest of the population<br />

from forming alternative, non-state forums to<br />

associate in. 10<br />

Iraqi states in the modern era have all<br />

been weak on the institutional level. Violence<br />

was commonly used to settle disputes among<br />

the ruling classes repeatedly: first in 1920 and<br />

1941, against the British, again in 1958 against<br />

the pro-British monarchy, and in 1963 with<br />

the establishment of the Baathist dictatorship.<br />

But the fierce state of Saddam Hussein was<br />

also weak in the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s<br />

because of the way the state was organized: as<br />

a "totalitarian, patrimonial system" that also<br />

"was an amalgam of a single-family and a<br />

8 Michael Barnett, “Building a Republican Peace:<br />

Stabilizing States after War,” International Security 30, no.<br />

4, (2006): 89, accessed May 5, 2014.<br />

http://ezproxy.library.nyu.edu:15301/eds/pdfviewer/p<br />

dfviewer?vid=9&sid=012545a9-6521-4dc9-915aa3e4383c5b05%40sessionmgr111&hid=104.<br />

9 Abbas Kelidar, “States without Foundations: The<br />

Political Evolution of State and Society in the Arab<br />

East,” Journal of Contemporary History 28, no 2 (1993):<br />

324, accessed May 5 2014.<br />

http://www.jstor.org/discover/10.2307/260713?uid=3<br />

739808&uid=2&uid=4&uid=3739256&sid=211037528<br />

35571.<br />

10 Nazih Ayubi, Over-Stating the Arab State: Politics and<br />

Society in the Middle East, (London and New York, I. B.<br />

Tauris, 1995: 22.<br />

80 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 80


single-party system.” 11<br />

A strong state structure, according to<br />

Abbas Kelidar, is necessary for the growth of<br />

nationalism. This has proven elusive in Iraq<br />

because “a powerful force of national and<br />

social mobilization has been incapable of<br />

serving as the foundation of political<br />

organization” due to a lack of shared<br />

historical identities within its borders. 12 Across<br />

the whole of the Middle East, multiconfessional<br />

political movements in other<br />

post-Ottoman Arab states often failed to<br />

agree on how to share power because the<br />

"state" was not seen as a legitimate<br />

participatory venue. The frequent recourse to<br />

violence suggested less a weak sense of<br />

nationhood than a dearth of acceptable<br />

power-sharing arrangements. 13 So, the contest<br />

for power among these factions has<br />

historically ended with one or two of them<br />

capturing the state and resorting to divideand-rule<br />

politics. These factions fail to agree<br />

on power-sharing arrangements, instead<br />

resorting to officially sanctioned violence to<br />

maintain the status quo and, for the<br />

persecuted have-nots, insurgency. 14<br />

The late dictator’s policies were not<br />

“conducive to the development of an<br />

integrative condition in which a coherent<br />

11 Faleh Jabar, Postconflict Iraq: A Race for Stability,<br />

Reconstruction, and Legitimacy, (Washington, D.C.: USIP,<br />

2004): 7, accessed May 5, 2014.<br />

http://www.usip.org/sites/default/files/sr120.pdf.<br />

12 Kelidar, “States without Foundations,” 320.<br />

13 As’ad AbuKhalil, “The Longevity of Arab Regimes:<br />

Causes of Oppression,” in Modern Middle East<br />

Authoritarianism: Roots, Ramifications, and Crisis. Eds.<br />

Benoun, Noureddine; Kia, Mehrdad; and Kirk, Mimi.<br />

(New York: Routledge, 2014). 50.<br />

14 North Yemen, now part of the Republic of Yemen,<br />

was another example of such a polity, a state where<br />

there was barely any “state” beyond the barracks.<br />

Whether under a monarch (before 1962), generals’<br />

clique (from 1974) or nepotistic family of bureaucrats<br />

(to 2011), coups were depressingly common in North<br />

Yemen because there was no other “accepted”<br />

mechanism for the transfer or modification of power.<br />

The North Yemeni state was also a fierce state, then.<br />

sense of political identity and stable political<br />

institutions could be established on firm<br />

foundations.” 15 Military institutions showed<br />

similar favoritism, failing to become vehicles<br />

for shared national identity given the high<br />

concentration of Sunni Arab officers and<br />

specialists (in other countries, like Lebanon or<br />

North Yemen, one could see Christians or<br />

Shia in similar positions). The Shia and<br />

Kurdish insurgencies in Iraq were, from the<br />

insurgents’ perspective, the only logical<br />

responses to this situation: to be<br />

acknowledged, they had to fight the state<br />

because no other form of protest was<br />

“legitimate.”<br />

“State-building in the Middle East”<br />

says Stephen Townley, “may function best at<br />

the sub-state level” precisely because it<br />

requires varied groups lacking a concrete<br />

national identity accepting that they need to<br />

agree on a set of rules to provision their own<br />

constituencies and then, moving forward,<br />

interact with others. 16 This has been how<br />

Iraqis have groped towards building a “new”<br />

Iraq since 2003: by attempting to renounce<br />

winner-take-all political violence in favor of<br />

negotiated transfers of authority and other<br />

arrangements, like revenue sharing. 17 The<br />

process is far from complete. Though the<br />

“nation” of Iraq is a fragile one, the real<br />

problem at hand is the failure of an Iraqi state<br />

to provide a secure space for citizens of<br />

different associations present to see<br />

themselves a part of, and have a stake in<br />

maintaining, the state even if it makes them<br />

more insecure and less privileged relative to<br />

other groups.<br />

15 Kelidar, “States without Foundations,” 327.<br />

16 Stephen Townley, “Perspectives on Nation-<br />

Building,” The Yale Journal of International Law 30, no.<br />

347 (2005: 359, accessed May 5, 2014.<br />

http://heinonline.org/HOL/LandingPage?handle=hei<br />

n.journals/yjil30&div=13&id=&page=.<br />

17 Bouillon, “Iraq’s State-Building Enterprise,” 292.<br />

81 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 81


THE IRAQ FIERCE STATE: FEET OF<br />

CLAY<br />

The Iraqi state was, in short, “over<br />

stated”: it was imagined to be much stronger<br />

than it was simply because it projected such<br />

an image. 18 So how were the Iraqi Baathists<br />

able to build a state that was, at its core,<br />

extremely weak as a set of institutions and<br />

norms despite its authoritarian longevity? The<br />

Baathist regime, set up in 1963, endured until<br />

2003, with only a short interruption of its rule<br />

in the late 1960s. The three basic conditions<br />

of the “fierce state” existed throughout this<br />

period. A “democracy of bread” that was the<br />

oil-subsidized welfare system, a brutal internal<br />

policing mechanism, and a rallying cry of<br />

exclusivist nationalism over competing<br />

ideologies such as communism, pan-Arabism,<br />

and Islamism. 19<br />

The Baathist authorities offered Iraqis<br />

a “choice,” so to speak: accept a social<br />

contract that stultifies civil society in exchange<br />

for welfarism. Such states appear strong, but<br />

rely on the consent of the (un)governed: any<br />

form of mass protest or security disturbance<br />

has the potential to bring down the whole<br />

edifice if not crushed immediately, which is<br />

why the Baath Party responded so brutally<br />

both to attempted insurgencies and the<br />

mildest forms of dissent. 20<br />

Joining the Baathist Party was a<br />

prerequisite for career advancement, and was<br />

predicated on stifling any unapproved or<br />

potentially disruptive associations. 21 The<br />

Punishment Law 111 (Section 200) of the<br />

Baath Party’s charter allowed the regime to<br />

sentence party members to death if a member<br />

had any unlicensed affiliations with other<br />

political movements in Iraq—which is to say,<br />

all of them. Special attention was also paid to<br />

inductees who had been active in any<br />

movement that was banned after 1968, since<br />

this meant they had had such associations. 22<br />

Informing on colleagues was encouraged, and<br />

torture was common as well. 23 All of this<br />

helped the state prevent the emergence of<br />

civil society by promoting distrust and<br />

isolation: members of Saddam Hussein's<br />

family were not even immune from such<br />

checks on their power if they were seen by<br />

him to have stepped out of line. 24 Even the<br />

military remained divided, under suspicion,<br />

and, given the shortages plaguing the country<br />

after 1991, a competitor in internal “politics.”<br />

Although Western and Arab intelligence<br />

services expected palace coups to take place<br />

against Saddam Hussein during the 1990s, the<br />

officer corps remained loyal to him.<br />

Uncivil society building in Iraq also<br />

meant breaking up tribal associations, because<br />

these could serve as the basis for reforms,<br />

demands, and agitation. Tribes were, and are,<br />

central to Iraqi political organization:<br />

“Saddam co-opted the tribal organizations<br />

that undergirded Iraq,” according to Peter<br />

Van Buren, “manipulating the local sheiks<br />

toward his own ends by giving power to<br />

some, money to others, and depriving those<br />

who crossed him of both.” 25 The Baath Party<br />

divided and ruled tribes by creating two levels<br />

of leadership within each of them that would<br />

18 Ayubi, Over-Stating the Arab State, 3.<br />

19 RAND, “Chapter Ten: Iraq,” 178.<br />

20 Stephen Kotki,. Uncivil Society: 1989 and the Implosion of<br />

the Communist Establishment, (New York: Random House<br />

Publishing Group, 2009): Kindle location 2776.<br />

21 Phebe Marr, “Where Is Iraq Headed?” American<br />

Foreign Policy Interests 25 (2003): 368, accessed May 7,<br />

2014.<br />

http://ezproxy.library.nyu.edu:15301/eds/pdfviewer/p<br />

dfviewer?vid=4&sid=012545a9-6521-4dc9-915aa3e4383c5b05%40sessionmgr111&hid=104.<br />

22 Mark Magnier, “Documents Reveal Extent of Baath<br />

Party Rule,” The Los Angeles Times, April 6, 2003,<br />

accessed May 2, 2014.<br />

http://articles.latimes.com/2003/apr/06/news/warbaath6.<br />

23 Marr, “Where Is Iraq Headed?” 370.<br />

24 AbuKhalil, “The Longevity of Arab Regimes,” 45.<br />

25 Peter Van Buren, We Meant Well: How I Helped Lose<br />

the Battle for the Hearts and Minds of the Iraqi People, (New<br />

York: Henry Holt and Co., 2011): Kindle location 75.<br />

82 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 82


e at odds with one another. 26<br />

Efforts to create a strong state in Iraq<br />

largely failed due to domestic political<br />

maneuverings, but uniquely among other<br />

fierce states in the Middle East, external<br />

factors had a significant impact. No other<br />

Middle Eastern dictatorship has ever been as<br />

sanctioned as Iraq between 1991 and 2003. 27<br />

These external factors crippled what state<br />

infrastructure did exist prior to 2003, and<br />

undermined (though did not collapse) uncivil<br />

society’s bargain with the state. Yet people's<br />

“strategies of survival” did become less<br />

dependent on state agencies than on the<br />

United Nations, their extended families, and<br />

local notables with access to humanitarian<br />

goods and permits. Saddam Hussein<br />

exacerbated these developments when he<br />

turned a blind eye to rampant government<br />

corruption to focus on placating his most<br />

important loyalists. As for the rest of the<br />

population, sixty percent of Iraqis lived below<br />

the poverty line by 2003, and an equal number<br />

received their daily bread from the UN's Oil<br />

for Food program. 28 Even the usually wellprovisioned<br />

internal security services were not<br />

unaffected: their duties in Baghdad Province<br />

increasingly fell to hastily deputized Sunni<br />

militias, simply due to the cost saving<br />

measures this move produced. 29<br />

While Baathism prevented the<br />

emergence of civil society under Saddam<br />

Hussein's rule, internal conflict did not “end”<br />

when the Baathist took power. Iraqi Shia,<br />

26 Williams, “Criminals, Militias, and Insurgents:<br />

Organized Crime in Iraq,” 26.<br />

27 RAND, “Chapter Ten: Iraq,”163.<br />

28 Hasan Latif Kathim al-Zubaydi, “Iraq's Poverty Since<br />

the 1980s—A Story of National Decline,” Niqash,<br />

January 9, 2007, accessed on May 5, 2014.<br />

http://www.niqash.org/articles/?id=1986.<br />

29 Eric Davis, “Sectarianism, Historical Memory, and<br />

the Discourse of Othering: The Mahdi Army, Mafia,<br />

Camorra, and ‘Ndrangheta,” in Uncovering Iraq:<br />

Trajectories of Disintegration and Transformation. Eds.<br />

Toensing, Chris and Kirk, Mimi, (Washington, D.C.:<br />

Center for Contemporary Arab Studies, 2010): 91.<br />

especially, continued to exist outside of the<br />

state structure and build their own networks,<br />

states within states. Kurdistan was effectively<br />

independent after 1995. These disputes could<br />

not simply be frozen by the regime’s policies,<br />

and exploded after 2003. 30 As one Iraqi man<br />

asked Foreign Service Officer Van Buren<br />

during his tour in Anbar Province, “when will<br />

you [Americans] close the door you opened in<br />

our country?” 31 This is the reality that the U.S.<br />

and Iraqis faced in 2003, “a plethora of social,<br />

institutional, economic, and cultural forces,<br />

hitherto dormant, emerged in full force”—<br />

and no one was ready for what came next. 32<br />

Sunnis have reacted to their diminished power<br />

by resorting to violence, which spurs Shias to<br />

press harder against them—while the Shias'<br />

act of holding onto power through force<br />

means they are fanning the flames of the<br />

Sunnis’ rejectionist position.<br />

It was extremely unlikely that national,<br />

democratic institutions could function<br />

effectively in these conditions. 33 They did not,<br />

and this outcome reflected an absence of<br />

“civic culture” among communities. The<br />

process has unfolded differently among<br />

various communities in Iraq, but several<br />

commonalities are present, and these play<br />

against one another across group actors.<br />

STATE COLLAPSE: THE SUNNI VIEW<br />

The Sunni experience in the “new”<br />

Iraq has been especially jarring, and indicative<br />

of the challenges of state building that Iraq<br />

faces. 34 The Sunnis in Iraq had, until 2003,<br />

been the ruling class, initially due to the Turks<br />

and the British. Though nationalist and<br />

secularist regimes after WWII tried to<br />

subsume Sunni identity in uncivil society<br />

30 Davis, “Sectarianism, Historical Memory, and the<br />

Discourse of Othering,” 93.<br />

31 Van Buren, We Meant Well, 90.<br />

32 Jabar, Postconflict Iraq, 14.<br />

33 Davis, “Sectarianism, Historical Memory, and the<br />

Discourse of Othering,” 67.<br />

34 Bouillon, “Iraq’s State-Building Enterprise,” 287.<br />

83 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 83


ased on patronage and the politics of fear,<br />

that privileged tribalism never disappeared. As<br />

noted above, Sunni tribal autonomy grew<br />

during the 1990s due to the impoverishment<br />

of the state after the First Gulf War. 35 Because<br />

they were denied the ability to form free<br />

associations, Sunni leaders had become used<br />

to in-group welfarism and corruption, the<br />

latter simply an extension of welfare and<br />

patronage politicking. This uncivil society was<br />

effectively forced to disband by the Coalition<br />

Provisional Authority (CPA) in 2003, putting<br />

over half a million people out of work. These<br />

men and women fell back on tribal, familial,<br />

and criminal network that had emerged in<br />

place of an authentic civil society. Forcing all<br />

of these individuals out of their jobs proved<br />

to be an undesirable undertaking from a<br />

security standpoint. It meant renegotiating a<br />

social contract and finding capable<br />

administrators in impossibly short time. 36<br />

Iraqis finally had the chance to build a civil<br />

society but could not depend on paid<br />

employment, safe travel, or even regular<br />

access to water and electricity.<br />

Then came the 2005 national<br />

elections. The electoral list that year was very<br />

closely identified with the CPA by Sunnis, as<br />

well as the U.S. and Iran more broadly, both<br />

of whom were resented for expanding their<br />

influence into the country. 37 The Sunnis had<br />

been stripped of power, while the Iraqi Shia—<br />

despite having experience organizing their<br />

communities—had never run anything at the<br />

national level. In this situation, the barriers to<br />

35 Williams, “Criminals, Militias, and Insurgents:<br />

Organized Crime in Iraq,” 26.<br />

36 Thomas E. Ricks, Fiasco: The American Military<br />

Adventure in Iraq, 2003 to 2005, (New York: Penguin<br />

Group US, 2006): Kindle location, 161-2.<br />

37 Bellin, “The Robustness of Authoritarianism in the<br />

Middle East: Exceptionalism in Comparative<br />

Perspective.” Comparative Politics 36:2, 2004.<br />

. Accessed 5<br />

May 2014. 150.<br />

national unity were tremendous because the<br />

short-term incentive for Iraqi politicians was<br />

to build up competing, exclusivist state<br />

capacities within their particular<br />

ethnosectarian associations. 38 In Sunni areas, a<br />

U.S. military survey noted at the time, “the<br />

vast middle ground does nothing to stop<br />

[Baathist insurgents] and to date does not see<br />

it in their interest to help us corner them.” 39<br />

Though the 2005 elections had been<br />

demanded by many Iraqi leaders—taken as a<br />

sign of a willingness to build a state where<br />

power would be contested through<br />

institutions—the process arguably ended in<br />

failure. 40 Those appointed were meant to<br />

represent a balance of émigré and domestic<br />

politicians, and the country’s largest ethnic<br />

groups. This approach was unreflective of the<br />

new social spaces emerging within the<br />

country. It signaled to Iraqis that the central<br />

state was not worth supporting, but was<br />

worth capturing. This led to some of the first<br />

waves of attacks on those associated with the<br />

occupation had focused on perceived<br />

collaborators with the occupying forces. 41<br />

Another significant challenge was that Sunnis<br />

simply refused to “buy in” to a unified state<br />

due to Shias controlling distribution of basic<br />

resources and welfare assistance.<br />

The Sunni tribal “Sons of Iraq”<br />

movement had the potential to be a<br />

significant moment in state building. It was,<br />

however, ultimately compromised by the<br />

inability of the central government to accept<br />

the legitimacy of the movement and give up<br />

some of its power by recognizing the Sons'<br />

security gains against their common enemy, al<br />

Qaeda in Iraq (AQI, now ISIL or the “Islamic<br />

State”). Prior to the movement's formation,<br />

38 Wayne White, “The Saga of Iraqi Electoral<br />

Disappointment,” LobeLog, May 8, 2014, accessed on<br />

May 8, 2014. http://www.lobelog.com/the-saga-ofiraqi-electoral-disappointment/.<br />

39 Ricks, Fiasco, 216.<br />

40 Jabar, Postconflict Iraq, 8.<br />

41 Ricks, Fiasco, 215.<br />

84 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 84


the incessant attacks on Sunni communities<br />

by Shia militias and AQI led many Sunnis to<br />

decide not to trust the new authorities since<br />

“the very force that was designed to protect<br />

them [the Iraqi national police] preyed on<br />

them instead.” 42 In response to this, and the<br />

depredations of AQI, Sunni leaders in the<br />

western reaches of the country began<br />

organizing themselves into self-defense<br />

leagues and soliciting U.S. assistance, which<br />

from 2007 to 2009, was provided in<br />

significant quantities. Yet when Sunni leaders<br />

went to Baghdad to obtain official blessing,<br />

the government of Nouri al-Maliki only<br />

reluctantly granted it. Maliki and his pro-Iran<br />

coalition had to be dragged into supporting<br />

the “Awakening.” 43 Baghdad eventually<br />

reneged on promises to integrate Sunnis from<br />

these self-defense units into the security<br />

apparatus, and the Shia-dominated police<br />

were especially hostile to them. This has<br />

become even more pronounced since 2014<br />

with the upgrading of many Shia militias’<br />

capabilities by the Baghdad government (and<br />

Iran) to take over counterinsurgency<br />

operations from the national army that<br />

collapsed before the onslaught of the Islamic<br />

State due to mass desertions. Though some<br />

token Sunni militias fight alongside these<br />

heavily armed irregulars, Shia formations like<br />

Katib Hezbollah and the Badr Organization<br />

far outnumber them and the regular Iraqi<br />

National Army forces, and have ethnically<br />

cleansed Sunni or Kurdish areas in the north<br />

and west of the country.<br />

Even before this, the Shia leadership<br />

saw few reasons, after the U.S. troop<br />

withdrawal negotiated by the Bush<br />

Administration took effect, to accede to<br />

further American pressure to recognize the<br />

Sons. This, in turn, convinced some Sunni<br />

42 Williams, “Criminals, Militias, and Insurgents:<br />

Organized Crime in Iraq,” 15.<br />

43 Thomas E. Ricks, The Gamble: General Petraeus and the<br />

American Military Adventure in Iraq, (New York: Penguin<br />

Group US, 2009): Kindle Locations 1456-1457.<br />

groups they were better off keeping their arms<br />

and rejecting vague promises of recognition<br />

and salaried positions. 44 The new wave of<br />

violence in the Sunni-majority Al Anbar<br />

Province that began in 2013—several years<br />

after the supposed success of the<br />

“Awakening”—was precipitated by the<br />

Baghdad authorities' cracking down on<br />

opposition Sunni politicians there. 45 Prior to<br />

that, as a result of the questionable 2010<br />

election results that returned Maliki to power,<br />

“Sunnis lost faith in the political process and<br />

the jihadists were once again able to make<br />

inroads among them.” 46<br />

STATE BUILDING: THE SHIA VIEW<br />

For Iraqis to accept the idea that “the<br />

costs of democratic politics [were] preferable<br />

to the costs of resorting to violence in terms<br />

of achieving their goals of acquiring power” is<br />

a tall order in light of their country’s history.<br />

But, Shia parties in the country have started to<br />

accept this principle to a degree. 47 This is<br />

because of a conscious decision to contest<br />

authority by becoming authority, rather than<br />

operating outside of the system.<br />

Unfortunately, intimidation and patronage are<br />

44 Joel Wing, “Continued Problems Integrating The<br />

Sons of Iraq,” Musings on Iraq, August 10, 2010,<br />

accessed on April 28, 2014.<br />

http://musingsoniraq.blogspot.com/2010/08/continu<br />

ed-problems-integrating-sons-of.html.<br />

45 Dexter Filkins, “What We Left Behind,” The New<br />

Yorker, April 28, 2014, accessed on May 7, 2014.<br />

http://www.newyorker.com/reporting/2014/04/28/1<br />

40428fa_fact_filkins?currentPage=all.<br />

46 Joel Wing and Peter Mansoor, “Inside The Surge An<br />

Interview With Prof Peter Mansoor Former Executive<br />

Officer To Gen Petraeus,” Musings on Iraq, December<br />

31, 2013, accessed on May 7, 2014.<br />

http://musingsoniraq.blogspot.com/2013/12/insidesurge-interview-with-prof-peter.html.<br />

47 Eric Davis, “Islamism, Authoritarianism, and<br />

Democracy: A Comparative Study of Egypt and Iraq,”<br />

in Modern Middle East Authoritarianism: Roots,<br />

Ramifications, and Crisis. Eds. Benoun, Noureddine; Kia,<br />

Mehrdad; and Kirk, Mimi, (New York: Routledge,<br />

2014), 218.<br />

85 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 85


still accepted means to contest others for<br />

power, whether against other Shia factions or<br />

those outside that community. Such actions<br />

have done little to foster a less-exclusivist<br />

ideal of nationalism. The paradox is that<br />

building a stronger central state has led to<br />

sub-national groupings increasing their power<br />

at the state’s expense by siphoning off<br />

resources. 48<br />

It is more appropriate to compare<br />

Shia militias and their affiliated<br />

political/welfare arms with criminal<br />

organizations than with purely sectarian<br />

vehicles for power. 49 The Shia leadership in<br />

Iraq as whole, despite sectarian and regional<br />

differences, has shared a common historical<br />

experience in that they had been ruled by<br />

foreigners, deliberately neglected by the state<br />

after independence, and viewed as inherent<br />

troublemakers or the indolent poor. Because<br />

successive governments in Baghdad “failed to<br />

demonstrate any form of civil commitment<br />

toward the local population,” multiple “extralegal<br />

social organizations” arose at the<br />

expense of a common national identity. 50<br />

Since the 1920s, Shia sectarian identity has<br />

hardened as community leaders built up their<br />

own state within a state to provide services to<br />

neglected communities. The Baathists'<br />

crushing of Iraqi nationalists, communists,<br />

and pan-Arabists after seizing power in 1963<br />

further solidified Shia identity. The Baathists<br />

destroyed actors who could or would bridge<br />

the gaps to the much larger Shia population.<br />

Once these movements were taken care of,<br />

active measures against prominent religious<br />

figures in the predominantly Shia cities of<br />

Najaf and Karbala began in earnest in the<br />

1970s. These sweeps culminated in a series of<br />

mass killings in 1992 following a failed<br />

48 Williams, “Criminals, Militias, and Insurgents:<br />

Organized Crime in Iraq,” 204.<br />

49 Davis, “Islamism, Authoritarianism, and<br />

Democracy”. 207.<br />

50 Davis, “Sectarianism, Historical Memory, and the<br />

Discourse of Othering,” 78.<br />

uprising in the south of the country by<br />

Iranian-backed Shia insurgents.<br />

After this failed uprising, Muqtada al-<br />

Sadr came to represent the new approach to<br />

politics and state building. His father,<br />

assassinated by the Baathist secret police in<br />

1999, had set the groundwork for him, by<br />

turning to the UN for relief aid under the<br />

sanctions regime and using this aid to<br />

organize a committed following. But, the elder<br />

al-Sadr differed from his predecessors who<br />

had founded Iraq’s first Islamist party (Da'wa)<br />

in that he sought to become part of the state<br />

apparatus in order to co-opt it. 51 The Sadrists’<br />

model was not unlike Hezbollah’s in Lebanon:<br />

a charity, an army, and an electoral list all at<br />

the same time. The divide was, according to a<br />

2003 report in The Baltimore Sun, between<br />

“older ayatollahs … counseling patience with<br />

the occupation” and “the younger faction<br />

[that] wants to found an Islamic state” around<br />

the younger al-Sadr. 52<br />

Sadr, who took a more conciliatory<br />

tone with the U.S.-backed government at the<br />

start than other aspiring political strongmen,<br />

revolted in 2004 after a crackdown on his<br />

organization. His forces took over local<br />

government offices and disarmed the police in<br />

Shia communities. 53 Faced with a determined<br />

U.S. response, Sadr eventually backed down<br />

and announced that he regarded the interim<br />

elections set for 2005 as legitimate. But his<br />

insurrection had proven a point. 54 Sadr was<br />

51 Robert Baer, The Devil We Know: Dealing with the New<br />

Iranian Superpower, (Crown Publishing Group, 2008):<br />

Kindle locations 731-3.<br />

52 New York Times News Service, “Blast kills 90, top<br />

Shiite cleric,” The Baltimore Sun, August 30, 2003,<br />

accessed on May 8, 2014.<br />

http://articles.baltimoresun.com/2003-08-<br />

30/news/0308300269_1_najaf-al-hakim-importantshiite.<br />

53 Marr, “Where Is Iraq Headed?” 366.<br />

54 Tareq Y. Ismael and Max Fuller, “The disintegration<br />

of Iraq: the manufacturing and politicization of<br />

sectarianism,” International Journal of Contemporary Iraqi<br />

Studies 2, no. 3 (2008): 465, accessed May 7, 2014.<br />

http://ezproxy.library.nyu.edu:15301/eds/pdfviewer/p<br />

86 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 86


very successful in building a shadow state that<br />

could and still does provide security for his<br />

followers. 55 Sadr, like other Shia leaders,<br />

decided in the wake of his initial military<br />

actions against the U.S. and its Iraqi<br />

collaborators that his organization had the<br />

chance to take “control of a state apparatus<br />

stripped bare by the looting,” in “an<br />

opportunity to obtain resources and benefits<br />

long denied them.” 56 So even as the country<br />

fell into civil war, some Shia leaders opted in<br />

to the U.S.-backed order. Even the popular<br />

Ayatollah Sistani, who had earlier railed<br />

against the country's first elections, reversed<br />

course and publicly backed the process.<br />

Acquiring control of the state would produce<br />

an even greater chance to provision the Shia<br />

community, so that by 2006, Prime Minister<br />

Nour al-Maliki led the opting-in of Iraqi Shia to<br />

form a central government. For Maliki and<br />

company the Americans “became adjudicator<br />

and enforcer in criminal disputes dressed up<br />

as political differences, siding with one set of<br />

violent armed groups engaged in criminal<br />

activities against other groups judged more<br />

dangerous.” 57 Sadr's militia, too, “bought in”<br />

when faced with the prospect of further<br />

armed conflict with the U.S. and Maliki's<br />

security services. His organization was<br />

ostensibly disbanded, with its gunmen folded<br />

into the security services or national<br />

parliament. Yet while it may have given up its<br />

paramilitary operations, the group’s political<br />

leaders remained committed to providing<br />

welfare services and “protection” to Shia<br />

communities in a long line of Shia state within<br />

a state activities. 58 In any event, the Sadrists<br />

remobilized their paramilitary wing in 2014 in<br />

dfviewer?vid=18&sid=012545a9-6521-4dc9-915aa3e4383c5b05%40sessionmgr111&hid=104.<br />

55 Ibid., 460.<br />

56 Williams, “Criminals, Militias, and Insurgents:<br />

Organized Crime in Iraq,” 202.<br />

57 Ibid., xv.<br />

58 Davis, “Sectarianism, Historical Memory, and the<br />

Discourse of Othering,” 96.<br />

order to fight the Islamic State after the<br />

national army’s repeated failures to do so.<br />

Although the Sadrist organizations<br />

decided that the best bet for their future was<br />

to sign on to a broader Shia bloc, they have<br />

long dropped hints that they are willing to<br />

return to the barricades. It is incorrect to<br />

imagine that Sadr has full control over them<br />

in this respect, or that his own followers’<br />

actions do not tie his hands because the<br />

organization has a very ill-defined power<br />

structure since it aspires to be a big tent<br />

movement over its rivals, including members<br />

of Sadr's own family. 59 “The Mahdi Army has<br />

become a worrisome burden on the Sadrist<br />

movement, which seeks to become a political<br />

faction that does not work with weapons,”<br />

reported an Iraqi journalist in 2013, adding<br />

that most of the movement’s leadership<br />

outside of Sadr’s own circle subscribes to the<br />

view that the electoral process cannot be<br />

trusted to protect their communities’<br />

security. 60 This sort of behavior is driven by<br />

lack of security, but it is also driven by the<br />

common themes of “political ambition, and<br />

the imperatives of resource generation” in a<br />

country where state capture is the objective of<br />

most organized political actors. 61<br />

The Sadrists and the current ruling<br />

coalition now find themselves confronted<br />

with Shia militias like Asaib Ahl al-Haq, which<br />

while declaring its support for a united Shia<br />

bloc in parliament uses intimidation to<br />

59 Harith Hasan, “Is Muqtada al-Sadr retiring or<br />

repositioning?” Al-Monitor, Transl. Rani Geha, Al-<br />

Monitor, February 21, 2014, accessed on May 7, 2014.<br />

http://www.almonitor.com/pulse/originals/2014/02/sadr-decisionretire-repositioning.html#ixzz312eE9Ld7.<br />

60 Ali Abel Sadah, “Sadr Reconsiders Political Role,<br />

Mahdi Army,” Transl. Sahar Ghoussoub, Al-Monitor,<br />

August 28, 2013, accessed on May 7, 2014.<br />

http://www.almonitor.com/pulse/originals/2013/08/iraq-clashesmahdi-army-asaib-ahl-al-haqsadr.html#ixzz312cdBVDx.<br />

61 Williams, “Criminals, Militias, and Insurgents:<br />

Organized Crime in Iraq,” xi.<br />

87 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 87


compete with its fellow Shia. 62 Within the Shia<br />

communities of Iraq, then, is a lack of<br />

acknowledgment for “a larger and more<br />

diverse cultural and political universe.” 63 Even<br />

at the height of his power, Maliki only directly<br />

controlled a few military units: he was<br />

otherwise very reliant on former members of<br />

the Badr Organization, who were at odds with<br />

the Sadrists. 64 A proliferation of such<br />

organizations weakens state structures and the<br />

idea of an “Iraqi nation” through<br />

parochialism. The Sadrists, in particular, are<br />

characterized by vigilantism and extensive<br />

local autonomy that cannot easily be reined<br />

in. 65 Newer groups formed in the wake of the<br />

army’s 2014 disasters, are much more<br />

assertive in using armed action to carve out a<br />

space for themselves. One of these new<br />

militia leaders, when asked by a reporter “will<br />

you train the security forces, or bring your<br />

own men?” in the event of further jihadist<br />

attacks on Shia communities said that he<br />

would bring his own men in. 66 Though there<br />

is no reason to doubt that sectarian beliefs are<br />

sincerely felt as part of their worldview, it is<br />

worth noting that religious fiat is merely the<br />

tool that paramilitaries use to win political<br />

power by force.<br />

62 Ali Mamouri, “The Rise of 'Cleric Militias' in Iraq.”<br />

Transl. Tyler Huffman, Al-Monitor, July 23, 2013.<br />

http://www.almonitor.com/pulse/originals/2013/08/iraq-clashesmahdi-army-asaib-ahl-al-haqsadr.html#ixzz312cdBVDx.<br />

63 Davis, “Sectarianism, Historical Memory, and the<br />

Discourse of Othering,” 69.<br />

64 Thomas E. Ricks, “The Best Defense Iraq, the<br />

unraveling (VI): looming intra-Shia violence?” Foreign<br />

Policy, April 24, 2009, accessed on May 5, 2014.<br />

http://ricks.foreignpolicy.com/posts/2009/04/24/ira<br />

q_the_unraveling_vi_looming_intra_shia_violence.<br />

65 Williams, “Criminals, Militias, and Insurgents:<br />

Organized Crime in Iraq,” 239.<br />

66 Watheq al-Battat, “Iraqi Shiite Militia Leader Watheq<br />

al-Battat: I Would Support Iran in a War against Iraq,”<br />

MEMRI, October 23, 2013, accessed on May 7, 2014.<br />

http://www.memri.org/clip_transcript/en/4046.htm.<br />

CONCLUSION: IRAQ’S<br />

INSTITUTIONAL ANEMIA<br />

As Toby Dodge writes, Iraq was<br />

imagined by its American occupiers as a<br />

country where the central government's<br />

“capacity is ultimately grounded in the extent<br />

to which its administrative staff successfully<br />

upholds the claim to the monopoly of the<br />

legitimate use of physical force in the<br />

enforcement of its order.” 67 The dictum that<br />

“the real goal is to create as many Iraqis as<br />

possible who feel they have a stake in the new<br />

Iraq” sounds like an effective solution, but the<br />

reality is that without an agreed-upon “Iraqi<br />

state,” the violence will continue within and<br />

among armed factions. 68 This underlines just<br />

how much the Government of Iraq has failed<br />

to create conditions conducive to the<br />

formation of a sense of national identity (or<br />

even sectarian identity) that, if felt across the<br />

political spectrum, would help reduce violence<br />

within Shia communities, and against outgroups<br />

like the Sunnis or other minorities by<br />

the Shia-dominated security services. 69<br />

A state structure that Iraqis of all<br />

creeds and ethnicities can accept as legitimate<br />

requires “space for societal actors to<br />

determine for themselves what the good life is<br />

and how to achieve it.” 70 Ultimately, the state<br />

can only be accepted as legitimate when it<br />

operates in “a regularized fashion.” 71 The only<br />

way forward is for civil society—which<br />

despite all of the setbacks and catastrophes of<br />

the past decade (and its stunting under<br />

67 Toby Dodge, “Iraq: the contradictions of exogenous<br />

state-building in historical perspective,” Third World<br />

Quarterly 27, no. 1 (2006): 189, accessed May 7, 2014.<br />

http://ezproxy.library.nyu.edu:15301/eds/pdfviewer/p<br />

dfviewer?vid=15&sid=012545a9-6521-4dc9-915aa3e4383c5b05%40sessionmgr111&hid=104.<br />

68 Ibid., 190.<br />

69 Dahr Jamail, “Maliki's Iraq: Rape, Executions and<br />

Torture,” Truthout, March 21, 2013, accessed May 20,<br />

2014. http://truth-out.org/news/item/15246-malikisiraq-rape-executions-and-torture.<br />

70 Barnett, “Building a Republican Peace,” 90.<br />

71 Bouillon, “Iraq’s State-Building Enterprise,” 290.<br />

88 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 88


Saddam Hussein and other autocrats) has<br />

grown tremendously with the loosening of<br />

censorship and state patronage—to develop,<br />

and learn “the arts of consensus building,<br />

[and] compromise.” 72 The challenge remains:<br />

that civil society move toward underwriting a<br />

state structure, especially, a working legislative<br />

process and a national army not beholden to<br />

different tribal leaders and bureaucratic<br />

factions.<br />

Now that some factions have started<br />

to grope towards a consensus of state power,<br />

they can no longer ride out in opposition and<br />

must make compromises to compete within<br />

the framework set by the central government.<br />

This often means cooperating with an outgroup<br />

and enforcing conformity among<br />

internal dissenters. Ideally, this should<br />

strengthen the community's sense of being<br />

protected by the state and thus, part of a<br />

single nation within the state's borders. But in<br />

order to placate core constituencies, some<br />

groups will brutalize and extort both Sunni<br />

and Shia citizens. Clearly, a civil society that<br />

does not resort to violence to win a share of<br />

the pie is still a long way off in light of the<br />

Shia parties’ recent debates over how to do<br />

just that. 73<br />

The door the Americans opened is<br />

not going to close anytime soon, so a<br />

“national identity” will likewise remain elusive,<br />

especially as the counterinsurgency against the<br />

Islamic State takes on a more sectarian<br />

character. Shia militias persecute all Sunnis in<br />

an area of operations, regardless of their<br />

complicity. Kurdish forces have evicted non-<br />

Kurds from their areas of operation for<br />

“security reasons,” and Sunni communities<br />

have turned on their non-Sunni neighbors,<br />

especially if they are part of Iraqi’s smallest<br />

minority groups (and therefore, the least<br />

militarily-organized or influential). The Iraqi<br />

state remains over stated, and increasingly, so<br />

is the concept of a common Iraqi nationality<br />

whose survival is now in much more doubt<br />

than it ever was during the first years of the<br />

Iraqi Civil War.<br />

PAUL MUTTER is a graduate student at NYU<br />

pursuing an MA in International Affairs. He is a<br />

blogger for the Foreign Policy Association, and<br />

also writes for War Is Boring, The Arabist and<br />

Souciant Magazine.<br />

72 Jabar, Postconflict Iraq, 16.<br />

73 Marr, “Where Is Iraq Headed?” 371.<br />

89 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 89


Power to the<br />

Babushkas?<br />

Reconsidering the Relationship<br />

between Russian Politics and<br />

the Elderly<br />

Ilaria Parogni<br />

“P<br />

arty for everybody! Dance!”<br />

This was the refrain of a song<br />

performed by Buranovskiye<br />

Babushki, a group of elderly women from<br />

the Russian village of Buranovo Udmurt<br />

Republic, during the 2012 Eurovision<br />

Song Contest. The number was a success,<br />

and the group finished in second place in<br />

the contest. 1 In the often-bizarre setting of<br />

Eurovision, the image of this colorful<br />

group of smiling grandmothers mixing<br />

folk tradition with pop seemed perfectly<br />

placed. Yet, it was much more difficult to<br />

conciliate it with the ideas most<br />

commonly associated with the elderly as<br />

the poor, disgruntled, and most progovernment<br />

segment of the Russian<br />

population. 2<br />

1 Eurovision Song Contest, About Buranovskiye<br />

Babushki (December 10, 2014),<br />

http://www.eurovision.tv/page/history/year/part<br />

icipant-profile/?song=26973.<br />

2 OECD. OECD Reviews of Labour Market and Social<br />

Policies: Russian Federation 2011 (December 2011):<br />

162, http://www.oecdilibrary.org/employment/oecd-reviews-of-labourmarket-and-social-policies_20743408;<br />

Denis Pinchuk, “Russian Pensioners Protest<br />

against High Food Prices,” Reuters (November 3,<br />

2007),<br />

http://www.reuters.com/article/2007/11/03/usprotest-russia-food-idUSL0312283020071103;<br />

This contrast reveals the power of<br />

stereotypes (and, yes, Buranovskiye<br />

Babushki themselves could be said to<br />

embody a stereotype) in shaping the ways<br />

in which observers cast an entire social<br />

group. In an attempt to go past the<br />

stereotypes associated with the Russian<br />

elderly as a homogeneous group of<br />

enfeebled victims of state neglect, I will<br />

explore the political significance of the<br />

elderly in contemporary Russia,<br />

highlighting the potential impact that<br />

members of this demographic can have<br />

on politics. 3 By looking at how voting<br />

patterns and issues related to Russian<br />

pensioners have both constrained and<br />

facilitated certain political outcomes, I will<br />

bring attention to the precariousness of<br />

the relationship between the Russian<br />

government and the country’s older<br />

citizens.<br />

In the first section, I will discuss<br />

the connection between politics and old<br />

age in Russia, focusing on the main<br />

themes defining their exchange and the<br />

challenges in researching this subject due<br />

to the limited scholarship and data<br />

available. In the second section, this<br />

report will offer an overview of instances<br />

in post-Soviet history from 1991 on that<br />

reveal recurring patterns in Russian<br />

politics vis-à-vis its senior citizens. In the<br />

final section, I will show how these<br />

patterns might be a destabilizing factor in<br />

the current political environment and a<br />

Aleksei Levinson, “The Institutional Framework<br />

of Old Age: Old Age as Gender,” Sociological<br />

Research 52, no. 3 (May–June 2013): 53.<br />

3 Aleksei Levinson, “The Institutional<br />

Framework,” 53;<br />

Andrea Chandler, “Democratization, Social<br />

Welfare and Individual Rights in Russia: The Case<br />

of Old-Age Pensions,” Canadian Slavonic Papers /<br />

Revue Canadienne des Slavistes 43, No. 4 (December<br />

2001): 429.<br />

90 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 90


potential danger to the longevity of the<br />

Putinist enterprise. As unfavorable<br />

economic circumstances are exacerbated<br />

by the imposition of economic sanctions<br />

by the West and declining oil prices, could<br />

Russia’s pensioners rise in revolt against<br />

the system?<br />

POLITICS AND OLD AGE: THEMES<br />

AND CHALLENGES<br />

Politics and society can interact in<br />

different ways depending on the political<br />

system in place and the level of<br />

development of civil society. In the<br />

majority of cases, however, this<br />

interaction is reciprocal—society defines<br />

and constrains politics as much as politics<br />

shapes society. This is, of course, also true<br />

of Russia. Various scholars, including<br />

Anna Arutunyan in The Putin Mystique, and<br />

Fiona Hill and Clifford Gaddy in Mr.<br />

Putin: Operative in the Kremlin, have adopted<br />

this outlook. 4 Both present in-depth looks<br />

4 Anna Arutunyan, The Putin Mystique. Inside Russia’s<br />

Power Cult. Northampton, (MA: Olive Branch<br />

Press, 2014).<br />

In her book The Putin Mystique, Arutunyan (2014)<br />

investigates the roots of Vladimir Putin’s popular<br />

regime. Her study delves into the inner workings<br />

of the Russian mind by analyzing the relationship<br />

between the ruled and the ruled. Arutunyan<br />

highlights the quasi-sacral aspect of this bond<br />

through a series of portraits of individuals<br />

belonging to different groups: the “subjects”<br />

(regular citizens), the “oprichniki” (the security<br />

apparatus), and the “boyars” (the oligarchs). The<br />

author looks back to history to highlight elements<br />

of continuity in Russia’s penchant for the cult of<br />

power and power leaders, highlighting how<br />

Russians experience state power as a “mystical<br />

entity” able to act to establish order when laws fail.<br />

In Arutunyan’s account, Putin exploits the<br />

mystique surrounding the figure of the president as<br />

a god-like figure.<br />

at the state established by Putin and his<br />

inner circle through the prism of his<br />

relationship with his subjects, thus<br />

discarding the view of the current regime<br />

as a monolithic dictatorship solely defined<br />

by those in power.<br />

The notion of society as a<br />

“victim” of politics is an easy trap to fall<br />

into when the elderly are involved,<br />

especially in Russia. Ever since the<br />

collapse of the Soviet Union, as the<br />

economic crisis engulfed the country,<br />

images of Russian babushkas<br />

(grandmothers) begging on the streets of<br />

Moscow have become tragically iconic.<br />

Pensions in Russia, for both civilian<br />

workers and military servicepeople, are<br />

Fiona Hill and Clifford J. Gaddy, Mr. Putin:<br />

Operative in the Kremlin, (Washington, D.C.:<br />

Brookings Institution Press, 2013).<br />

In Mr. Putin: Operative in the Kremlin, Hill and Gaddy<br />

(2013) offer an overview of Russia under Putin<br />

through a thoughtful analysis of various identities<br />

associated with the Russian leader. Each identity –<br />

the Statist, the History Man, the Survivalist, the<br />

Outsider, the Free Marketer, and the Case Officer<br />

– is connected with a specific moment in Putin’s<br />

personal history. In their assessment, the various<br />

identities define Putin’s role as CEO of the<br />

country as a corporate empire (“Russia, Inc.”) in<br />

which the private commercial interests are tied<br />

together with those of the Russian state. The result<br />

is a state that operates on two levels: the formal<br />

political institutions and the informal system,<br />

“which provides access to prestigious positions<br />

and a whole array of perks and privileges,<br />

including the possibility of self-enrichment” (p. 5).<br />

The authors argue that the model envisaged,<br />

however, cannot work on a mass scale because the<br />

widespread corruption that prevents the model<br />

from functioning is also the glue that holds the<br />

system in place.<br />

91 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 91


extremely low by European standards. 5<br />

Foreign and Russian media often<br />

emphasize the struggles and gloomy<br />

outlook faced by the older portion of the<br />

population. 6 And yet, anyone who has<br />

visited Russia over the last few years will<br />

likely have encountered the feisty and<br />

tougher side of the country’s senior<br />

citizens, be it in the form of a pensioner<br />

chanting communist slogans at a protest<br />

or a museum guard shouting at the<br />

tourists getting too close to the paintings<br />

in St. Petersburg’s Hermitage Museum.<br />

Scholars have replicated the<br />

tendency to assume that the Russian<br />

elderly are passive victims by depriving<br />

them of attention as agents of change. No<br />

study thus far has captured the ways in<br />

which the relationship between the state<br />

and the elderly is structured in Russia.<br />

Most of the scholarship dedicated to<br />

issues affecting Russian pensionery<br />

(pensioners) focuses on pension law and<br />

reform, often taking a top-down approach<br />

to these issues. 7 Even when scholars have<br />

been able to appreciate that the exchange<br />

5 The Associated Press, “How Retirement Systems<br />

Vary, Country to Country,” Finance Yahoo,<br />

(December 30,<br />

2013),http://finance.yahoo.com/news/retirementsystems-vary-country-country-055009752.html;<br />

Andrew E. Kramer, “Russia Raises Some Salaries<br />

and Pensions for Crimeans,” The New York Times,<br />

(March 31, 2014),<br />

http://www.nytimes.com/2014/04/01/world/eur<br />

ope/russia-raises-pensions-for-crimeans.html.<br />

6 “What it means to get old in Russia,” RT (Russian<br />

Today), (February 10, 2011),<br />

http://rt.com/news/old-russia-elderly-people/.<br />

7 For example: Linda J. Cook, Postcommunist Welfare<br />

States: Reform Politics in Russia and Eastern Europe,<br />

(Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2007);<br />

Theodore P. Gerber and Jonas Radl (2014).<br />

“Pushed, Pulled, or Blocked? The Elderly and the<br />

Labor Market in Post-Soviet Russia,” Social Science<br />

Research 45 (May 2014): 152-169.<br />

is far from unilateral, as is the case with<br />

Andrea Chandler’s 2004 study of pension<br />

reform in post-Soviet Russia, this<br />

approach has not developed into a deeper<br />

study of the relationship. 8<br />

There is an absence of a solid<br />

body of qualitative and quantitative data<br />

analyzing the political behavior of the<br />

elderly, which partly explains why scholars<br />

have paid little attention to the issue. Only<br />

a few surveys focus on political attitudes<br />

and preferences by age group in Russia,<br />

and polling data on the voting behavior of<br />

the elderly is even rarer. 9 Moreover, an<br />

analysis of electoral results and data issued<br />

by Russian government organizations<br />

cannot avoid facing questions regarding<br />

the veracity of the materials available due<br />

to repeated reports of fraud and<br />

irregularities in the Russian electoral<br />

process. 10<br />

It is therefore important to initiate<br />

a discourse on this topic. While academics<br />

still debate the possibility of a recovery<br />

from the demographic crisis that hit<br />

Russia in the 1990s, it is now increasingly<br />

difficult to argue against the idea of its<br />

population growing older as life<br />

expectancy and fertility rate continue to<br />

8 Andrea Chandler, Shocking Mother Russia:<br />

Democratization, Social Rights, and Pension Reform in<br />

Russia, 1990-2001, (Toronto, Canada: University of<br />

Toronto Press, 2004).<br />

9 “Faktory Elektoral’nogo Vybora,” FOM<br />

(December 18, 2003),<br />

http://bd.fom.ru/report/cat/elect/parl_el/dd034<br />

929;<br />

“Vyborye Prezidenta: Kak Golosovali Sotsialnye<br />

Gruppy.” Levada Tsentr (March 27, 2012):<br />

http://www.levada.ru/27-03-2012/vyboryprezidenta-kak-golosovali-sotsialnye-gruppy.<br />

10 James Balls, “Russian Election: Does the Data<br />

Suggest Putin Won Through Fraud?” The Guardian,<br />

(March 5, 2012),<br />

http://www.theguardian.com/news/datablog/201<br />

2/mar/05/russia-putin-voter-fraud-statistics.<br />

92 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 92


ise. 11 Moreover, the notion according to<br />

which Russian pensioners are among the<br />

most politically active segments of the<br />

population and some of Putin’s most loyal<br />

supporters has become so commonplace<br />

both in academia and the media that it<br />

deserves to be put to the test.<br />

A HISTORICAL OVERVIEW<br />

In Soviet times, the Russians<br />

developed the country’s first national old<br />

age pension system, and kept improving<br />

benefits for selected categories of<br />

workers. 12 The cornerstone of the Soviet<br />

approach to pensions was the 1956<br />

Pension Law, which made the state solely<br />

responsible for pensions and guaranteed<br />

pensions automatically after a certain<br />

number of years spent working. 13 The<br />

system might have prevented the<br />

accumulation of personal wealth, but it<br />

was fairly generous and, above all,<br />

universal. 14<br />

With the dissolution of the USSR,<br />

the situation worsened dramatically for<br />

the Russian elderly. Even before the<br />

collapse, social scientists and economists<br />

11 Max Fisher, “Did Russia Just Overcome Its 20-<br />

Year Demographic Crisis?” The Washington Post<br />

(November 1, 2012),<br />

http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/worldvie<br />

ws/wp/2012/11/01/did-russia-just-overcome-its-<br />

20-year-demographic-crisis/;<br />

Aleksei Levinson, “The Institutional Framework,”<br />

53.<br />

12 Andrea Chandler, Shocking Mother Russia, 24.<br />

13 Andrea Chandler, “Democratization, Social<br />

Welfare,” 418.<br />

14 Linda J. Cook, Postcommunist Welfare States, 2;<br />

John B. Williamson and Michelle L. Maroto, “The<br />

Political Economy of Pension Reform in Russia: Why did<br />

Russia Adopt the World Bank Model?” Presented at<br />

100th Annual Meeting of the American<br />

Sociological Association held in Philadelphia, PA,<br />

August 13-16 (2005): 3.<br />

among the proponents of Mikhail<br />

Gorbachev’s perestroika had included the<br />

pension law among the targets of their<br />

restructuring efforts. 15 After 1991, a<br />

reform program was supposed to be<br />

gradually implemented between 1990 and<br />

1992, but, as aptly pointed out by<br />

Chandler, the situation was “overtaken by<br />

events.” 16 The adoption of “shock<br />

therapy” under Boris Yeltsin and the<br />

economic crisis that followed directly<br />

affected the life of the population at large,<br />

with poverty, inequality, and<br />

unemployment growing exponentially. 17<br />

By 2001, Chandler had identified the<br />

plight of pensioners in Russia as “one of<br />

the most tragic social consequences of the<br />

collapse of communism.” 18<br />

The elderly were among the most<br />

severely affected, with their meager<br />

pensions losing their value as inflation<br />

wiped out many families’ savings.<br />

Payments were increasingly delayed, as the<br />

budget deficit inherited from the<br />

communist era became unbearable. 19<br />

Meanwhile, the liberalization process was<br />

investing politics too. Competitive<br />

elections, as well as the competition<br />

between the legislative power represented<br />

by the State Duma and the executive<br />

power of the presidency before 1993,<br />

ensured that discussion of poverty among<br />

the elderly became a highly politicized<br />

issue. 20<br />

15 Linda J. Cook, Postcommunist Welfare States, 56.<br />

16 Andrea Chandler, “Democratization, Social<br />

Welfare,” 423.<br />

17 Linda J. Cook, Postcommunist Welfare States, 63.<br />

18 Andrea Chandler, “Democratization, Social<br />

Welfare,” 409.<br />

19 Andrea Chandler, Democracy, Gender, and Social<br />

Policy in Russia: A Wayward Society. (Croydon, UK:<br />

Palgrave Macmillan, 2013): 87.<br />

20 Andrea Chandler, “Democratization, Social<br />

Welfare,” 423.<br />

93 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 93


From this point of view, Russia’s<br />

senior citizens were among the “victims”<br />

of circumstances. On a different level,<br />

however, one could argue that politicians<br />

were equally constrained by their reliance<br />

on popular support. In his essay “The<br />

Collapse of Civility in Russia: The Young<br />

and Aged in a Failed Society,” Ronald E.<br />

Jones illustrates how maintaining support<br />

among the older portion of the population<br />

was considered essential by the Soviet<br />

authorities, as a generous pension and full<br />

employment were the two core values of<br />

the system. 21 In an attempt to maintain<br />

this support, they would rely on shortterm<br />

solutions, such as increasing<br />

pensions to specific groups of workers,<br />

without considering the structural changes<br />

that would have been required for the<br />

system to become sustainable in the long<br />

run. 22<br />

This tendency to rely on shortterm<br />

solutions has, according to Chandler,<br />

become an institutionalized habit in<br />

Russia. 23 As the pension arrears threatened<br />

Yeltsin’s popularity ahead of the 1996<br />

presidential elections, for example, the<br />

Russian president publicly condemned the<br />

issue and used his authority to unblock<br />

the payments. 24 His inner circle fully<br />

supported this measure.<br />

Another issue that Yeltsin had to<br />

face was the emergence of the elderly as<br />

an active force in the political arena. In<br />

particular, as pensioners disillusioned with<br />

capitalism filled the ranks of the<br />

Communist Party of Russia, as well as the<br />

smaller Party of Pensioners, opposition<br />

parties made the protection of pensioners’<br />

rights a top platform plank. 25 This directly<br />

threatened Yeltsin’s position in power, as<br />

many of those who had personally<br />

experienced the disastrous consequences<br />

of the economic crisis opposed his<br />

reelection, supporting Communist leader<br />

Gennady Zyuganov instead as he<br />

promised a return to Soviet-style<br />

welfarism. Many have argued that Yeltsin<br />

might have lost, had he not relied on the<br />

oligarchs to rig the elections. 26<br />

CAN RUSSIAN PENSIONERS<br />

BRING DOWN THE SYSTEM?<br />

A defining aspect of the<br />

relationship between the state and the<br />

elderly in Russia is the fact that economic<br />

concerns have often created situations of<br />

imbalance, with discontent leading to<br />

active opposition. As argued by Chris<br />

Gilleard and Paul Higgs in The Power of<br />

Silver: Age and Identity Politics in the 21 st<br />

Century, while political militancy among<br />

the elderly has failed to materialize in the<br />

West, it is much more likely to develop in<br />

post-Communist countries. 27 This partly<br />

explains the narrative according to which<br />

Putin has the support of the older<br />

population, since his arrival on the<br />

political scene coincided with the gradual<br />

improvement of the economic situation<br />

within the country. The favorable<br />

economic conditions allowed the Russian<br />

leader to complete the deferred reform of<br />

the pension system with the introduction<br />

of a centralized national pension fund.<br />

21 Ronald E. Jones, “The Collapse of Civility in<br />

Russia: The Young and Aged in a Failed Society,”<br />

Sociological Inquiry 72, Issue 3 (Summer 2002): 413.<br />

22 OECD, OECD Reviews, 3.<br />

23 Andrea Chandler, Shocking Mother Russia, 26.<br />

24 Andrea Chandler, “Democratization, Social<br />

Welfare,” 430.<br />

25 Stephen White, “Soviet Nostalgia and Russian<br />

Politics,” Journal of Eurasian Studies 1(2010): 7.<br />

26 Anna Arutunyan, The Putin Mistique, 174.<br />

27 Chris Gilleard and Paul F. D. Higgs, “The<br />

Power of Silver: Age and Identity Politics in the<br />

21st Century,” Journal of Aging & Social Policy<br />

21(2009), 12.<br />

94 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 94


The system transitioned towards a “multipillar<br />

arrangement,” bringing together<br />

features of different pension schemes,<br />

including mandatory and voluntary<br />

provisions, as well as a pay-as-you-go<br />

system of contributions and pre-funding<br />

to finance benefits. 28 This coincided with<br />

visible improvements in the lives of<br />

Russian pensioners that happened to<br />

coincide with the reforms’ timing: most<br />

arrears in pensions and benefits were<br />

eliminated, and the average pension rose<br />

above the above subsistence level. 29<br />

Yet even Putin approached the<br />

elderly with care, cultivating support<br />

among the interested parties through<br />

public speeches and pension increases,<br />

timed to coincide with the introduction of<br />

the reforms. 30 Moreover, the government<br />

was able to absorb the Party of Pensioners<br />

within the “managed opposition”—<br />

showing the importance placed on<br />

defusing its political independence.<br />

Having merged with other two parties to<br />

form “Just Russia,” the Party of<br />

Pensioners led by Igor Zotov left this bloc<br />

in 2012 to form the Russian Pensioners<br />

For Justice Party. 31 The “new” pensioners’<br />

party has consistently supported Vladimir<br />

Putin and United Russia. 32<br />

All of this effort on the<br />

government’s part might be justified.<br />

After all, Russian pensioners have gone<br />

rogue under Putin before. When a law<br />

came into effect in 2005 that replaced<br />

28 OECD, OECD Reviews, 174.<br />

29 Linda J. Cook, Postcommunist Welfare States, 150.<br />

30 Andrea Chandler, Shocking Mother Russia, 143;<br />

157.<br />

31 “Istoriya Partii,” Rossiyskaya Partiya Pensionerov za<br />

Spravedlivost, http://www.ppzs.ru/2013-06-23-14-<br />

42-57/история6-23-14.<br />

32 “Rossiyskaya Partiya Pensionerov,” FOM<br />

(March 31, 2005),<br />

http://bd.fom.ru/report/map/projects/dominant<br />

/dom0513/dd051332/printable/.<br />

longstanding social benefits (including<br />

free public transportation and healthcare)<br />

with monthly cash payments, groups of<br />

pensioners took to the street to express<br />

their opposition to it. In a comment piece<br />

published in The Nation, Katrina vanden<br />

Heuvel described the protests as “the<br />

largest, angriest and most passionate since<br />

Putin came to power,” hinting that they<br />

could pose a serious challenge to the<br />

stability of his regime. 33 The Russian<br />

leader’s response—doubling increases in<br />

pension payments and reintroducing free<br />

public transport—proved that Russian<br />

pensioners could exact concessions from<br />

the authorities much more than previously<br />

imaged. 34 This approach brings to mind the<br />

policies pursued by the leader of another<br />

post-Soviet country: the Belarusian<br />

president Alexander Lukashenko. In<br />

power since 1994, and dubbed by the<br />

West as “Europe’s last dictator,” has often<br />

relied on the country’s older demographic<br />

groups for support. To maintain his<br />

power base, throughout the years he has<br />

repeatedly increased pensions. 35 President<br />

Lukashenko has fully embraced the image<br />

33 Katrina vanden Heuvel, “Babushkas vs. Putin,”<br />

The Nation (January 20, 2005),<br />

http://www.thenation.com/article/babushkas-vsputin.<br />

34 Claire Bigg, “Protests Across Russia Force Putin<br />

to Double Increase in Pension Payments,” The<br />

Guardian, (January 18, 2005),<br />

http://www.theguardian.com/world/2005/jan/19<br />

/russia.<br />

35 “Pensions Increased by 15.3 Per cent in<br />

Belarus,” BBC Monitoring International Reports<br />

(September 22, 1998);<br />

President of the Republic of Belarus, Alexander<br />

Lukashenko Signs Decree on Raising Pensions, (October<br />

24, 2014):<br />

http://president.gov.by/en/news_en/view/alexan<br />

der-lukashenko-signs-decree-on-raising-pensions-<br />

10065.<br />

95 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 95


of president as champion of the elderly,<br />

speaking out, for example, against the<br />

unpopular proposal of increasing the<br />

country’s retirement age. 36 The Belarusian<br />

strategy, while feasible in the short term,<br />

however, could prove financially<br />

unsustainable in the future, as highlighted<br />

in a 2009 study by the European<br />

Commission. 37 In contrast, Ukraine, a<br />

country facing severe economic and<br />

security issues, has had to deal with<br />

pressure from Europe to take a tougher<br />

stance in the pension sector. In March<br />

<strong>2015</strong>, the Ukrainian government approved<br />

pension cuts alongside a whole set of<br />

other austerity measures, hoping to get<br />

financial help from the IMF in exchange. 38<br />

Pensions in Ukraine were lower than in<br />

Russia even before the cuts, as proved by<br />

the increase in pension size experienced<br />

by the residents of Crimea following the<br />

Russian annexation of the peninsula in<br />

2014 and their adjustment to Russian<br />

rates. 39 Ever since Putin’s return to the<br />

presidency in 2012, Russian experts have<br />

36 “Lukashenko Speaks against Raising Retirement<br />

Age in Belarus,” Belarus Bureau Prime-Tass (March<br />

16, 2012), http://www.primetass.by/english/print.asp?id=98447.<br />

37 European Commission, Social Protection and Social<br />

Inclusion in Belaru (2009),<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/social/BlobServlet?docId=43<br />

46&langId=en.<br />

38 Anastasia Forina, “Verkhovna Rada Revises $20<br />

Billion Budget, Cuts Pensions in Hopes of $25<br />

Billion in Loans,” Kyiv Post (March 13, <strong>2015</strong>),<br />

http://www.kyivpost.com/content/politics/verkh<br />

ovna-rada-revises-20-billion-budget-cuts-pensionsin-hopes-of-25-billion-financial-aid-382405.html.<br />

39 Andrew E. Kramer, “Russia Raises Some<br />

Salaries and Pensions for Crimeans,” The New York<br />

Times (March 31, 2014),<br />

http://www.nytimes.com/2014/04/01/world/eur<br />

ope/russia-raises-pensions-forcrimeans.html?_r=2.<br />

noted how the government has moved<br />

closer to the Russian Orthodox Church<br />

and presented itself as the promoter of<br />

traditional values and nationalism. To<br />

some, like Arutunyan, this was a move<br />

aimed at creating a split within the<br />

opposition. 40 Yet, it could be argued that<br />

the move is also a way to capture the<br />

favor of the part of the population that<br />

traditionally has a more conservative<br />

outlook on the issues targeted, including<br />

homosexuality and respect for religious<br />

authorities. Putin’s nod to the patriotic<br />

sentiment of the country, as embodied by<br />

the great fanfare that surrounds<br />

celebrations honoring World War II<br />

veterans, can be explained in a similar<br />

way. 41<br />

Finally, looking at the mass<br />

protests that took place in Russia between<br />

2011 and 2013, it is also important to<br />

notice that they saw the participation of<br />

people belonging to all age groups: the<br />

young, the middle-aged, and the elderly. 42<br />

So far, this essay has highlighted<br />

the patterns that dominate the relationship<br />

between the Russian authorities and the<br />

elderly. The main goal of this approach<br />

has been to provide foundation to the<br />

thesis according to which the current<br />

situation in Russia might prove to be a<br />

defining moment for the country’s<br />

politics, and that one of the reasons for<br />

this might be the complexity of the<br />

exchange between politics and the older<br />

segment of population.<br />

Against the backdrop of the<br />

Ukrainian crisis, Russia faces severe<br />

40 Anna Arutunyan, The Putin Mystique, 266.<br />

41 “Putin Thanks WWII Veterans for Their<br />

Heroism during War,” ITAR-TASS (May 9, 2014),<br />

http://itar-tass.com/en/russia/731040.<br />

42 Anton N. Oleinik, “Mass Protests in the<br />

Context of the Russian Power Regime,” Russian<br />

Social Science Review 54, no. 3 (May- June 2013), 2.<br />

96 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 96


economic issues, including rampant<br />

inflation, an impending recession, and<br />

declining oil prices. The situation has been<br />

exacerbated by the introduction of<br />

economic sanctions by Western countries<br />

in response to Russia’s position over<br />

Crimea. 43 In response to the economic<br />

downturn, the Russian government has<br />

targeted pensions in particular. In August<br />

2014 the government dipped into pension<br />

funds, diverting $8 billion in contributions<br />

earmarked for retirement schemes<br />

towards government spending. 44 In<br />

October 2014, in an even more<br />

controversial move, the Russian State<br />

Duma passed in its first reading a bill,<br />

known as the Rotenberg Law, which<br />

would allow citizens and companies who<br />

have lost property abroad due to the<br />

economic sanctions to seek<br />

reimbursement from the state. 45<br />

According to both Western and Russian<br />

media, it is likely that the money to<br />

finance the refunds will be taken from<br />

pension funds. 46 Former Finance Minister<br />

43 Moody’s, Moody's: Russia Sanctions Exacerbate the<br />

Country's Economic Challenges But Liquidity Crisis<br />

Unlikely in the Short-Term (July 14, 2014),<br />

https://www.moodys.com/research/Moodys-<br />

Russia-sanctions-exacerbate-the-countryseconomic-challenges-but-liquidity--PR_305457.<br />

44 Allison Schrager, “Unlike Russia, the U.S.<br />

Government Won't Take Your Pension Outright,”<br />

Bloomberg Businessweek (August 18, 2014),<br />

http://www.businessweek.com/articles/2014-08-<br />

18/russia-seized-citizens-pension-funds-dot-couldthat-happen-in-the-u-dot-s-dot.<br />

45 Sam Skove, “Russia's State Duma Passes Law<br />

Compensating Western Asset Seizures in First<br />

Reading,” The Moscow Times (October 8, 2014),<br />

http://www.themoscowtimes.com/business/articl<br />

e/russias-state-duma-passes-law-compensatingwestern-asset-seizures-in-firstreading/508651.html.<br />

46 Alexey Eremenko, “Cabinet Wants to<br />

Compensate Russian Victims of 'Illegal' Asset<br />

Seizures Abroad,” The Moscow Times (2014,<br />

Alexei Kudrin has severely condemned<br />

the renewed reliance of the government<br />

on pension savings as a move that<br />

threatens the long-term stability of the<br />

system. 47 “The concentration of resources<br />

at the expense of long-term stability—this<br />

is the result of the view that the task is to<br />

‘withstand’ the next two or three years,”<br />

Kudrin wrote in a column for Russian<br />

newspaper Kommersant. 48<br />

Kudrin’s words echo the<br />

considerations made in this essay<br />

regarding the tendency showed by Russian<br />

authorities towards preferring short-term<br />

solutions over long-term planning.<br />

Moreover, as previously highlighted, the<br />

relationship between politics and Russia’s<br />

senior citizens tends to shift whenever the<br />

economic conditions undergo a dramatic<br />

change—like it is the case in today’s<br />

Russia. The behavior of the Russian<br />

government, willing to return on its steps<br />

when facing discontent among the elderly,<br />

due to its unpopular policies, proves that<br />

Russian pensioners are perceived as a<br />

volatile yet important segment of the<br />

population. And while it is true, as<br />

pointed out by Mariya Riekkinen of<br />

Finland’s Åbo Akademi University, during<br />

October 2, 2014),<br />

http://www.themoscowtimes.com/business/articl<br />

e/russian-government-backs-rotenberg-bill-toblunt-western-sanctions/508304.html;<br />

Moskovskiy Komsomolets, Krepostnaya Rossiya<br />

(October 2, 2014),<br />

http://www.mk.ru/politics/2014/10/02/krepostn<br />

aya-rossiya.html.<br />

47 Reuters, “Kudrin Joins Growing Criticism of<br />

State's Use of Pension Savings,” The Moscow Times<br />

(August 8, 2014),<br />

http://www.themoscowtimes.com/business/articl<br />

e/kudrin-joins-growing-criticism-of-state-s-use-ofpension-savings/504810.html.<br />

48 Alexey Kudrin, “Pravila Igry,” Kommersant<br />

(August 8, 2014),<br />

http://www.kommersant.ru/doc/2540459.<br />

97 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 97


a Skype interview in November 2014, that<br />

today’s pensioners will not be affected by<br />

Russia’s decision to dip into pensions<br />

funds, the situation sets the scene for a<br />

future in which the elderly might see their<br />

pensions threatened. 49<br />

One must also not forget the fact<br />

that Russian pensioners have consistently<br />

proved to be politically active and<br />

heterogeneous in their approach to<br />

politics. 50 From Communists to convinced<br />

Putinists, from anti-Putin liberals to<br />

grandparents who rarely vote, the elderly<br />

will turn out on the streets to protest. This<br />

could prove to be a double-edged sword<br />

for Putin. Even though so far he has<br />

proven to be able to control the political<br />

outcome and has restrained discontent<br />

among the elderly, such a multi-layered<br />

social group can become unpredictable in<br />

situations of crisis and more difficult to<br />

manage.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

According to the views of the<br />

economists of The Russian Presidential<br />

Academy of National Economy and<br />

Public Administration (RANEPA), Russia<br />

is too old for a revolution. 51 RANEPA<br />

bases its assumption on two main<br />

observations: that the group of Russians<br />

aged 55 and older will grow much more<br />

solidly than the other age groups, and that<br />

in the 2012 presidential elections the<br />

majority of older votes went to Putin.<br />

RANEPA is only one of the many<br />

organizations guilty of oversimplifying the<br />

49 Skype interview with Mariya Riekkinen, Åbo<br />

Akademi University, Finland on November 17,<br />

2014.<br />

50 Aleksei Levinson, “The Institutional<br />

Framework,” 55.<br />

51 “Rossiya Slishkom Stara Dlya Revolutsiya,”<br />

Finmarket.ru (December 13, 2013),<br />

http://www.finmarket.ru/main/article/3577467.<br />

relationship between Russian politics and<br />

the elderly.<br />

As illustrated in this essay,<br />

scholars, the media and politicians too<br />

often regard the elderly as victims and<br />

subjects of the state, rather than as<br />

participating actors with the potential to<br />

push for policy changes. At the same time,<br />

the relationship between the Russian<br />

government and its pensioners remains<br />

understudied. This led to an<br />

underestimation of the complexities of<br />

this relationship and their relevance when<br />

trying to assess and predict the ways in<br />

which the current political situation in<br />

Russia will evolve.<br />

It is for this reason that this report<br />

recommends a framework that highlights<br />

a few features in the relationship that<br />

might hint at a shift in the balance.<br />

Namely, Russia’s tendency to rely on<br />

short-term solutions instead of focusing<br />

on long-term stability; the defining quality<br />

of economic factors in shaping the ways<br />

in which the government is constrained by<br />

or able to rely on the support of the<br />

elderly; the high levels of political activism<br />

and the heterogeneity of the politically<br />

active pensioners as a complicating factor<br />

in Russia’s attempt to manage the<br />

opposition. As the economic climate<br />

deteriorates further, those elements can<br />

become increasingly important. The fall of<br />

the ruble’s value and a food ban on some<br />

Western imports in response to the<br />

sanctions appear to have driven up the<br />

cost of basic foods, which is a major<br />

concern for the elderly given their special<br />

dietary needs and fixed incomes. 52 A 2014<br />

money-saving health care reform<br />

52 “Russians Feel the Pinch of Rising Food Prices<br />

as Inflation Bites,” The Moscow Times (February 19,<br />

<strong>2015</strong>),<br />

http://www.themoscowtimes.com/article.php?id<br />

=516256.<br />

98 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 98


threatens the quality of the services<br />

delivered by Russian hospitals. 53 All are<br />

issues that promise to become primary<br />

concerns for the elderly.<br />

So, is Russia “too old for a<br />

revolution?” It is unlikely that Russian<br />

babushkas will be the force driving an<br />

actual revolution, especially if one<br />

subscribes to the theory according to<br />

which Russia’s revolutionary path has<br />

more often being forged by the<br />

intellectual and/or political elites rather<br />

than by the masses. 54 Yet, the complexity<br />

of the relationship between politics and<br />

the elderly shows that the ground might<br />

be fertile for a disruption of the status<br />

quo. For that, Russia might just be old<br />

enough.<br />

53 Nataliya Vasilyeva, Thousands of Hospital Staff to Be<br />

Sacked in Russian Healthcare Reforms (November 28,<br />

2014),<br />

http://www.independent.co.uk/news/world/euro<br />

pe/thousands-of-hospital-staff-to-be-sacked-inrussian-healthcare-reforms-9891710.html.<br />

54 Sergei V. Kulikov, “Revolutions Invariably<br />

Come from Above. The Fall of Tsarism through<br />

the Prism of the Elite Circulation Paradigm,”<br />

Russian Studies in History 47, no. 4 (<strong>Spring</strong> 2009), 8–<br />

39.<br />

99 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 99


FURTHER READING:<br />

Arutunyan, Anna. The Putin Mystique. Inside<br />

Russia’s Power Cult. Northampton,<br />

MA: Olive Branch Press, 2014.<br />

Chandler, Andrea. Shocking Mother Russia.<br />

Democratization, Social Rights, and<br />

Pension Reform in Russia, 1990-2001.<br />

Toronto, Canada: University of<br />

Toronto Press, 2004.<br />

Cook, Linda J. Postcommunist Welfare States.<br />

Reform Politics in Russia and Eastern<br />

Europe. Ithaca: Cornell University<br />

Press, 2007.<br />

Gerber, Theodore P. and Radl, Jonas.<br />

Pushed, Pulled, or Blocked? The<br />

Elderly and the Labor Market in<br />

Post-Soviet Russia. Social Science<br />

Research 45, 2014.<br />

Hill, Fiona and Gaddy, Clifford J. Mr.<br />

Putin: Operative in the Kremlin.<br />

Washington, D.C.: Brookings<br />

Institution Press, 2013.<br />

Oleinik, Anton N. Mass Protests in the<br />

Context of the Russian Power<br />

Regime. Russian Social Science<br />

Review, vol. 54, no. 3, May–June,<br />

2013.<br />

vanden Heuvel, Katrina. Babushkas vs.<br />

Putin. The Nation. January 20,<br />

2005.<br />

ILARIA PAROGNI is an MA candidate in<br />

Journalism and Russian and Slavic<br />

Studies at New York University. She<br />

graduated with honors from University<br />

College London with a BA in European<br />

Social and Political Studies. Previously,<br />

she served as Director of Social Media at<br />

Russia Beyond the Headlines and was<br />

the co-founding editor of The Kompass, a<br />

website on Russian culture in the UK.<br />

Her work has been published by the<br />

Huffington Post, The Telegraph, Russia<br />

Direct, NewEurasia.net, Bedford &<br />

Bowery and others.<br />

100 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 100


From Multi-Party to<br />

Two-Party System<br />

The Applicability of Duverger’s<br />

Law and the Taiwanese Election<br />

Reform<br />

Pei-Yu Wei<br />

T<br />

he Republic of China (ROC), more<br />

commonly known and accepted as<br />

Taiwan, has been ruled by the<br />

Kuomintang (KMT) for the greater part of<br />

its history. After the Nationalist Party fled to<br />

the island of Taiwan following the loss of<br />

China to the Mao-led Chinese Communist<br />

Party, the KMT froze the constitution<br />

granting voting rights to citizens. It was not<br />

until 1986 that the government lifted its<br />

restrictions on political participation, and<br />

the first direct presidential election was not<br />

held until 1996.<br />

The elections of the Legislative<br />

Yuan, the highest legislature body in<br />

Taiwan, were also democratized in 1992,<br />

and the majority of legislators were elected<br />

under the Single Non-transferable Vote<br />

System (SNTV). Under the SNTV system, a<br />

voter casts one vote for one candidate in a<br />

multi-candidate race for multiple seats, and<br />

the candidates with the highest number of<br />

votes are elected. 1 In 2004, electoral reforms<br />

were put into place due to increasing public<br />

pressure against the negative aspects of the<br />

SNTV system, which included the<br />

cultivation of party factions and the<br />

opportunities for radical candidates who<br />

held niches in agendas and target only a<br />

specific minority to be elected. 2<br />

1 Specifically, of the 225 members, 168 were elected<br />

under the SNTV system, 8 were elected to represent<br />

the aboriginal population, 8 were elected to represent<br />

overseas Chinese under proportional representation,<br />

and 41 were elected under proportional<br />

representation.<br />

2 Hans Stockton, “How Rules Matter: Electoral<br />

Reform in Taiwan,” Social Science Quarterly 91, no. 1<br />

(2010): 21-41.<br />

Among the changes undertaken<br />

were the halving of the number of<br />

legislators to 113, and switching to a system<br />

of mixed member parallel (MMP), in which<br />

voters essentially participate in two separate<br />

elections, with one ballot for parties where<br />

the seats are decided through proportional<br />

representation, and another ballot for<br />

candidates where the winners are decided on<br />

a first-past-the-post basis. In the new<br />

system, 73 constituency seats are decided<br />

through the single member district (SMD)<br />

system, and 34 seats from party lists are<br />

decided through proportional<br />

representation. In addition, the party seats<br />

are allocated proportionally for parties that<br />

have gained at least five percent of the total<br />

party votes cast in the election cycle. The<br />

new system was enacted in the 2008<br />

Legislative elections. 3<br />

This paper will examine the<br />

applicability of Duverger’s Law on the<br />

electoral system before and after the reform.<br />

Duverger believes that under proportional<br />

representation systems, voters will be<br />

induced to vote based on their own<br />

preferences. However, under plurality<br />

systems, where only the candidate with the<br />

most vote(s) win the position, people tend<br />

to vote “strategically” for the candidate that<br />

they believe has the best chance of winning.<br />

This paper finds that while the law generally<br />

holds for the SNTV system and the SMD<br />

component of Taiwan’s MMP system,<br />

namely the constituent vote, the smaller<br />

parties’ ability to be represented in the<br />

legislature are actually being constricted,<br />

contradictory to the intention of Duverger’s<br />

Law. The paper will be divided into three<br />

components. First, it will briefly outline the<br />

theory of Duverger’s Law and the<br />

methodology applied in the paper. Then, an<br />

empirical analysis from the data available<br />

will follow. It will draw comparisons and<br />

provide explanations of the differences<br />

between the two results and between the<br />

results and expectations of the theory.<br />

3 Jih-wen Lin, “The Politics of Reform in Japan and<br />

Taiwan,” Journal of Democracy 17, no. 2 (2006): 118-<br />

131.<br />

101 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 101


Lastly, possible explanations for the<br />

deviations of the actual outcomes from the<br />

predicted ones will be offered, and<br />

conclusions drawn.<br />

DUVERGER’S LAW AND METHODOLOGY<br />

Duverger’s Law links the number of<br />

parties to the electoral system. Duverger<br />

finds that two-party systems often develop<br />

under plurality voting rules, in which every<br />

person only has one vote to cast for a<br />

candidate competing for a single seat in a<br />

district or a region (this is also known as the<br />

SMD system) 4 . Duverger provides two<br />

reasons for this phenomenon: the “fusion”<br />

or the coming together of weak parties to<br />

retain competitiveness, and the elimination<br />

of the weaker parties by the stronger parties<br />

through their superior resources and voters’<br />

strategic voting. Proportionality as electoral<br />

rule, on the other hand, encourages the<br />

formation of multi-party systems, since<br />

voters understand that their votes are more<br />

likely to influence the formation of the<br />

government. It is not impossible for twoparty<br />

systems to form, but it is<br />

comparatively more difficult under<br />

proportionality systems than it is under<br />

plurality systems. These observations<br />

combined make up what is known as<br />

Duverger’s Law.<br />

From these two rules further<br />

expectations could be inferred about<br />

different systems. In the SNTV system,<br />

similar to the SMD, voters only have one<br />

vote, with the major difference being that<br />

there are multiple seats up for contest.<br />

Hence, Duverger’s Law, when applied to<br />

SNTV, predicts that in districts with M seats<br />

open for election, there will be M+1 viable<br />

candidates contesting for them. 5 The<br />

empirical study on the SNTV system in<br />

4 Maurice Duverger, “Factors in a Two-Party and<br />

Multiparty System,” in Party Politics and Pressure<br />

Groups: A Comparative Introduction, Maurice Duverger<br />

(New York: Thomas Y. Crowell, 1972), 23-32.<br />

5 Steven R. Reed, “Structure and Behaviour:<br />

Extending Duverger's Law to the Japanese Case,”<br />

British Journal of Political Science 20, no. 3 (1990): 335-<br />

356.<br />

Taiwan done by Hsieh and Niemi provides<br />

evidence to support this. It also shows that<br />

the larger the district magnitude, the lower<br />

the level of strategic voting, since it would<br />

be more difficult for candidates and voters<br />

to calculate the probabilities of winning. 6<br />

This means that the more seats that are up<br />

for grabs in a single district, the more the<br />

voters will vote based on their real<br />

preferences and not because they believe<br />

that certain candidates stand higher chances<br />

of winning. Thus, in larger districts, the<br />

results will be more proportional in nature,<br />

and with a higher possibility of having more<br />

than M+1 candidates competing.<br />

Although there have not been many<br />

studies done on the applicability of<br />

Duverger’s Law to mixed systems, it is still<br />

possible to formulate expectations to the<br />

outcomes of the elections. Since Taiwan’s<br />

system is an unlinked parallel one (MMP),<br />

there is a relatively clear separation between<br />

the proportional representation (PR) and the<br />

SMD aspects of the ballots. It is true that in<br />

a mixed system, the party leaders or<br />

decision-makers may have other<br />

considerations. These include the placement<br />

of candidates on the party list or running in<br />

constituencies, and of candidates deciding<br />

whether to vie for a higher place on the<br />

party list or run in “safe constituencies.”<br />

However, for voters, since the party vote<br />

and the constituent vote are largely<br />

unconnected, it is safe to assume that their<br />

decisions for the two votes would also be<br />

separated instead of being interconnected.<br />

This is because voters do not need to<br />

consider the effects of splitting their ballots<br />

among different parties or candidates on the<br />

overall representation of their preferred<br />

parties. Therefore, for the SMD portion of<br />

the seats, we can expect to observe the<br />

dominance of two parties, while for the PR<br />

seats we can expect to see the presence of<br />

smaller parties, as per Duverger’s theory.<br />

Whether the system leans towards a two-<br />

6 John Fuh-sheng Hsieh and Richard G. Niemi, “Can<br />

Duverger’s Law be Extended to SNTV? The Case of<br />

Taiwan’s Legislative Yuan Elections.” Electoral Studies<br />

18, no. 1 (1999): 101-116.<br />

102 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 102


party system or a multi-party system<br />

depends on the relative ratio of the PR seats<br />

and the SMD seats. 7<br />

This paper will utilize the data of the<br />

Legislative Yuan elections from 1992 to<br />

2012, which comprises seven election cycles,<br />

because 1992 was the first year of direct<br />

legislative elections. Thus, to avoid the<br />

problem of regime change, this paper will<br />

not consider the data before 1992. The next<br />

section will examine the makeup of the<br />

different legislatures for each election cycle,<br />

a general empirical pre-reform and postreform<br />

comparison.<br />

EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS<br />

This section will analyze the seven<br />

Legislative Yuan elections individually, and<br />

then the pre-reform and post-reform<br />

differences will be examined<br />

comprehensively. Due to the number of<br />

new parties participating in each election<br />

cycle and the fluidity of small parties, apart<br />

from the few large parties that have<br />

maintained a somewhat steady presence in<br />

the elections since democratization, the<br />

majority of the parties participating in<br />

Legislative elections have changed from year<br />

to year. Hence, instead of recording the<br />

number of seats, or the percentage of seats<br />

that each party took in the elections, this<br />

section will explore the relative proportion<br />

of “small” to “large” parties in the<br />

Legislative Yuan. The “large” parties refer to<br />

the two main parties, the Kuomintang and<br />

the Democratic Progressive Party (DPP),<br />

while the rest of the contending parties are<br />

defined as “small” parties. By using this<br />

method, consolidation of, or the lack of, the<br />

two-party system can be more clearly<br />

calculated, instead of being distracted by<br />

minor issues.<br />

The first direct legislative election<br />

was held in 1992. Figure 1 shows the<br />

relative votes that each party gained in the<br />

election. 8<br />

Although 15 parties participated in<br />

the election, only four were able to gain<br />

seats in the legislature. The KMT was able<br />

to gain a majority, winning 59 percent of the<br />

seats, with the DPP lagging behind at 31.7<br />

percent. Together, the smaller parties, the<br />

China Social Democratic Party, and the<br />

independent candidates only managed to<br />

win 9.3 percent of the seats.<br />

In the 1995 election cycle (shown in<br />

Figure 2), the smaller parties did relatively<br />

better. Although the KMT still maintained a<br />

majority, retaining 51.8 percent of the seats,<br />

7 Misa Nishikawa and Erik S. Herron. “Mixed<br />

Electoral Rules’ Impact on Party Systems,” Electoral<br />

Studies 23, no. 4 (2004): 753-768.<br />

8 All the data on Taiwan elections utilized in this<br />

paper are sourced from the Taiwan Central Election<br />

Commission Database at<br />

http://engweb.cec.gov.tw/bin/home.php, and from<br />

Adam Carr’s Election Archive at http://psephos.adamcarr.net/.<br />

103 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 103


the DPP managed to improve its<br />

performance, clinching 32.9 percent of the<br />

seats, and the “small” parties, including<br />

independents, won 15.2 percent of the seats.<br />

The number of parties contesting for seats<br />

also drastically decreased to seven, which is<br />

understandable given the lackluster<br />

performance of small parties in the first<br />

direct legislative election.<br />

The 1998 election cycle, impacted by<br />

the first direct presidential election two<br />

years before, saw an increase in the number<br />

of small contending parties. 12 parties<br />

nominated candidates for election, among<br />

which eight managed to gain seats (see<br />

Figure 3).<br />

Union, which together made up 26.2<br />

percent of the Legislative Yuan. Such drastic<br />

change in the makeup can be attributed to<br />

the 2000 presidential election in which<br />

Taiwan elected a non-KMT president for<br />

the first time in history. This opened up<br />

rooms for people to consider other non-<br />

KMT party candidates, and boosted the<br />

confidence of smaller parties.<br />

While the KMT increased its seat<br />

share to 54.7 percent, the DPP managed to<br />

keep 31.1 percent of the seats. Although the<br />

“small” parties and independents only<br />

gained 14.2 percent, six parties (counting<br />

independents as a party) shared the<br />

percentage of seats.<br />

The 2001 election is an important<br />

turning point because it marked the end of<br />

KMT’s continual one-party dominance in<br />

the legislature. From Figure 4, it can be<br />

observed that the KMT not only lost its<br />

absolute majority, but also became the<br />

second-largest party at 30.2 percent of the<br />

total seats falling short of DPP’s 38.7<br />

percent. In addition, the number of seats<br />

that the “small” parties and independents<br />

hold dramatically increased, mainly due to<br />

the votes garnered by the newly-created<br />

People’s First Party and Taiwan Solidarity<br />

The 2004 election followed the same<br />

pattern, with no one single party managing<br />

to gain a majority (see Figure 5). Again, all<br />

the participating parties managed to secure<br />

seats in the legislature. Apart from the<br />

addition of the Non-Party Solidarity Union,<br />

all the parties that partook in the 2001<br />

election also participated in 2004.<br />

Nonetheless, the “small” parties’ seat<br />

decreased to 24.9 percent, as opposed to<br />

31.1 percent in 2001.<br />

The next election, held in 2008,<br />

marked the first post-reform Legislative<br />

Yuan election post-reform. Again, with the<br />

104 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 104


change in the electoral system, many smaller<br />

parties were encouraged to seek their<br />

chances, and thus the election cycle saw 14<br />

parties in total, including independents,<br />

contesting for legislative seats. However,<br />

only six out of the 14 were able to<br />

successfully gain seats. From Figure 6, we<br />

can see that the KMT once again regained<br />

its majority, holding 69.2 percent of the total<br />

seats, while the DPP held 23.1 percent,<br />

giving these two largest parties 92.3 percent<br />

of the total Legislative Yuan seats.<br />

The skewed partisan shift in the<br />

election is most likely due to the<br />

unpopularity of the DPP at the time, not<br />

entirely resulting from strategic<br />

considerations on the part of the voters.<br />

To break down the results further,<br />

from Figure 7 we can observe that none of<br />

the “small” parties managed to successfully<br />

gain a party seat, in spite of the fact that 12<br />

fielded candidates.<br />

According to Figure 8, a few “small”<br />

parties have managed to successfully put<br />

candidates into the legislature even though<br />

the DPP and the KMT together made up<br />

92.2 percent of the constituency and<br />

aboriginal seats,<br />

The pattern of large parties<br />

dominating the legislature could again be<br />

seen in the 2012 election cycle. As seen in<br />

Figure 9, the KMT and the DPP again took<br />

up 93.7 percent of the seats, an increase<br />

from 2008. Disenchanted by the 2008<br />

election, only six of the more successful and<br />

established parties fielded candidates to vie<br />

for seats in the Legislative Yuan, and as such<br />

all six managed to place candidates into the<br />

legislature.<br />

Unlike the election of 2008,<br />

however, the DPP and the KMT together<br />

only managed to retain 85.3 percent of the<br />

party seats in 2012, while the People First<br />

Party and the Taiwan Solidarity Union<br />

managed to split the rest (Figure 10). Figure<br />

11 shows, however, that 97.4 percent of the<br />

constituency and aboriginal seats went to<br />

the two largest parties, almost completely<br />

squeezing out the “small” parties.<br />

105 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 105


Table 1.<br />

Large<br />

Small<br />

Year parties<br />

parties<br />

1992 90.70 % 9.30 %<br />

1995 84.80 % 15.20 %<br />

1998 85.80 % 14.20 %<br />

2001 68.90 % 31.10 %<br />

2004 75.10 % 24.90 %<br />

2008 92.30 % 7.70 %<br />

2012 93.70 % 6.30 %<br />

Figure 12 and the corresponding<br />

Table 1 display the relationship between the<br />

“large” parties and the “small” parties<br />

throughout the seven elections. It can<br />

clearly be seen that, apart from the first<br />

direct legislative election (1992), pre-reform<br />

“small” parties always retained at least 14<br />

percent of the legislative seats, obtaining<br />

more than 30 percent of the seats at times.<br />

However, post-reform, the proportion of<br />

“small” parties shrunk dramatically down to<br />

less than 10 percent. The difference was all<br />

the more striking given the two preceding<br />

election cycles where the “small” parties<br />

managed to gain unprecedented victories.<br />

The next section will examine whether this<br />

change is in adherence to Duverger’s law, or<br />

whether there are indeed results that are<br />

unexpected by the theory.<br />

SNTV vs Mixed Member System<br />

Given what we already know about<br />

Duverger’s Law and its speculations<br />

concerning the results of SNTV, SMD, and<br />

PR systems (discussed in the second<br />

section), it is not difficult to examine its<br />

applicability to the recorded results of the<br />

Taiwanese legislative elections. This section<br />

will first apply Duverger’s Law to the prereform<br />

system, and then discuss its<br />

predicted results and the actual results in the<br />

post-reform system.<br />

While Taiwan was still under the<br />

SNTV system, the “small” parties held<br />

relatively large proportion. Though the<br />

“small” parties only contributed slightly<br />

over 9 percent of the total legislative seats in<br />

1992, it could be attributed to the voters<br />

getting used to their new found democracy.<br />

Afterwards, the “small” parties managed to<br />

gain footholds. This is compatible with<br />

Duverger’s Law in relation to the SNTV<br />

106 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 106


system. It proposes that the larger the<br />

district magnitude or the number of<br />

representatives from one district elected to a<br />

legislative body, the more proportional the<br />

election results would be. By default, smaller<br />

parties and independents would have a<br />

higher chance to be elected. Taiwan has<br />

comparatively large district magnitudes, with<br />

almost half of the districts having more than<br />

three representatives, with the highest at 17,<br />

which rounds to an average of 5.6. 9 Given<br />

that the literature suggests that strategic<br />

voting fades out when the district magnitude<br />

is larger than 5, 10 the vibrancy of the “small”<br />

parties in the pre-reform period is not<br />

surprising. However, I argue that<br />

unprecedented successes experienced by the<br />

“small” parties in the 2001 and 2004<br />

elections were not the norm, since<br />

disenchantment with the KMT and the<br />

exuberance of electing the first non-<br />

Nationalist president shifted voters’ support<br />

towards other smaller parties during that<br />

particular period of time, resulting in a<br />

rather unique period of multi-party presence<br />

in the Legislative Yuan.<br />

In the post-reform period, it is also<br />

easy to find Duverger’s Law at play. It is<br />

evident that strategic voting is at work since<br />

the “small” parties and independents did<br />

only manage to gain less than 10 percent of<br />

the constituency and aboriginal seats. The<br />

SMD districts have effectively restricted and<br />

stifled the chances of “small” parties being<br />

able to win votes, whereas previously in the<br />

SNTV system they were able to target niche<br />

voter groups. This and the very small<br />

proportion of PR seats that already existed<br />

in the pre-reform system in all likelihood<br />

contributed to the seemingly more<br />

majoritarian trend that accompanied the<br />

electoral reforms. However, at a closer look,<br />

it seems that the constituency seats were not<br />

the only places where smaller parties were<br />

9 John Fuh-sheng Hsieh and Richard G. Niemi, “Can<br />

Duverger’s Law be Extended,” 101-116.<br />

10 Thomas Gschwend, “Institutional Incentives for<br />

Strategic Voting and Party System Change in<br />

Portugal,” Portuguese Journal of Social Science 6, no. 1<br />

(2007): 15-31.<br />

constrained. Duverger’s Law asserts that<br />

when a PR system is present, instances of<br />

strategic voting decrease, and smaller parties<br />

have more opportunity to win seats in the<br />

legislature. However, the exact opposite<br />

happened in Taiwan. The seats of the<br />

smaller parties reduced dramatically in the<br />

party list portion of the mixed system. For<br />

2008, the party seats were entirely made up<br />

of the KMT and the DPP, while in 2012,<br />

the two parties constituted around 85<br />

percent of the party seats. Though the<br />

dominance of the “large” party had receded<br />

somewhat and the “small” parties’<br />

performance in the party seats this year was<br />

certainly better than in the constituency<br />

seats, only two smaller parties managed to<br />

gain enough votes to be allocated with party<br />

seats, leaving two other parties without any<br />

representative. This is a far cry from the<br />

expectations that Duverger’s Law provides.<br />

This paper will now examine the<br />

puzzle of why the smaller parties’ seats<br />

constricted simultaneously with the<br />

constituency seats, despite the fact that one<br />

is under a PR system and the other is under<br />

the SMD system.<br />

POSSIBLE EXPLANATIONS FOR THE<br />

REDUCTION OF PARTY SEATS FOR<br />

SMALLER PARTIES<br />

While electoral theory helps to<br />

predict the results of the elections, there are<br />

still a number of reasons that would induce<br />

the outcomes to deviate from the expected<br />

ones. This section offers possible<br />

explanations for the deviation of outcomes.<br />

The explanations are: the existence of<br />

strategic voting, the political contexts of<br />

partisan ideology, the relatively high social<br />

homogeneity and the growing maturity of<br />

the Taiwanese democracy, the confusion of<br />

voters, and finally, the switching of<br />

allegiances to large parties by small party<br />

members.<br />

While the PR system is supposed to<br />

encourage voters to vote in a “truthful”<br />

manner, strategic voting nevertheless<br />

persists. In the Taiwanese context, the 5<br />

percent of total votes threshold that parties<br />

have to pass in order to be allocated with<br />

107 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 107


seats in the Legislative Yuan could have<br />

induced voters to act strategically. If voters<br />

believed that there was a chance that the<br />

party that they support would not make the<br />

threshold, it is likely that they would<br />

deserted their party in favor of larger parties<br />

that is more likely to place their candidates<br />

into the legislature. Granted, gaining 5<br />

percent of the total votes was not an<br />

incredibly high mark to meet at the time,<br />

and in fact most “small” party leaders<br />

supported it, but the results show that the<br />

threshold was in fact oftentimes<br />

insurmountable for most of the smaller<br />

parties. It would seem, therefore, that the<br />

effects of strategic voting were larger than<br />

expected, and to find out why that is, a<br />

closer look needs to be taken at the political<br />

context of Taiwan.<br />

Political contexts of nations have<br />

always played a huge part in shaping the<br />

outcomes of elections, and are often the<br />

main contributing reasons why the election<br />

results were not as predicted. Taiwan stands<br />

in stark contrast in that the partisan line is<br />

not divided down left or right, but along<br />

pro-China and anti-China ideologies. While<br />

it is true that there are several variations of<br />

communist parties in Taiwan, these are also<br />

defined by their pro-Beijing leanings as<br />

opposed to their socio-economic ideals.<br />

Furthermore, in spite of the fact that most<br />

tend to associate the KMT with political<br />

elites and old money families, and the DPP<br />

with comparably less well-off voter groups<br />

such as agricultural producers, neither party<br />

could be clearly situated on a liberalconservative<br />

spectrum, unlike political<br />

parties in other countries. 11 Both parties<br />

have candidates who support issues such as<br />

gay rights, abortion, death penalty, and more<br />

expansive social welfare. One example of<br />

the interchangeability of ideological stance<br />

in the socio-economic aspect of the parties<br />

is the abolishment of tax breaks for<br />

government employees, specifically public<br />

school teachers and military personnel. The<br />

11 Weiming Tu, “Cultural Identity and the Politics of<br />

Recognition in Contemporary Taiwan,” The China<br />

Quarterly 148 (1996): 1115-1140.<br />

DPP first raised the issue of abolishing tax<br />

breaks for these public servants, since most<br />

of these positions were held by people<br />

whom DPP considered were from the<br />

privileged class that descended from the<br />

Mainland Chinese who escaped to Taiwan<br />

to get away from the civil war, and that<br />

these government employees were<br />

benefiting from the hard-earned money of<br />

local Taiwanese. When the policy was<br />

announced, it caused an outcry amongst the<br />

affected groups, which were also KMT’s<br />

strongest voter base, and this resulted in the<br />

DPP postponing its plans. However, when<br />

KMT resumed power in 2008, due to wide<br />

societal pressure against the perceived<br />

privileged class, the Nationalists had to push<br />

ahead with DPP’s ban on tax breaks.<br />

This unclear divide also extends to<br />

the “small” parties. Taiwan Solidarity Union,<br />

concerned with the localization of the<br />

Taiwanese people, is perhaps a bit more<br />

extreme on the anti-China scale, while the<br />

People’s First Party has had cozier relations<br />

with China than the KMT does. However,<br />

apart from this one clear ideological divide,<br />

the policies of the “small” parties are more<br />

often than not interchangeable with the<br />

dominant parties,’ and together the pro-<br />

China and the anti-China parties form the<br />

pan-blue and pan-green coalitions,<br />

respectively. 12 “Small” parties that focus on<br />

particular issues, such as the Green Party on<br />

environmental issues, have never had<br />

particularly strong preferences. Therefore it<br />

is quite easy for voters to switch party<br />

allegiances within the same coalition, which<br />

induces strategic voting behavior, or makes<br />

any considerations of strategic behavior<br />

easier for the calculus of the voters.<br />

Furthermore, Taiwan is a relatively<br />

homogenous society, which according to<br />

Moser (2001) would constrain the number<br />

of political parties in existence. 13 Although<br />

12 Ching-Hsin Yu, “The Evolving Party System in<br />

Taiwan, 1995-2004,” Journal of Asian and African<br />

Studies 40, no. 1-2 (2005): 105-123.<br />

13 Robert G Moser, Unexpected Outcomes: Electoral<br />

Systems, Political Parties, and Representation in Russia<br />

(Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 2001).<br />

108 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 108


there are clear differences between the<br />

demands and the needs of the aboriginals<br />

and the ethnically Chinese citizens, reserved<br />

seats for representatives of the indigenous<br />

population effectively alleviated the want for<br />

separate parties that specifically fight for the<br />

rights of the aborigines. The second divide<br />

in the Taiwanese society would be the<br />

“new” Mainland Chinese immigrants who<br />

fled from China in the late 1940s and the<br />

“old” Taiwanese whose ancestors had<br />

crossed the straits around five hundred years<br />

ago. Again, the “new” immigrants are the<br />

major supporters of the KMT and the “old”<br />

Taiwanese people make up a large<br />

proportion of the DPP voter base. The<br />

existing two parties, the pan-blue and pangreen<br />

coalitions, already adequately<br />

represent the distinct interests of these two<br />

different groups of voters, thus limiting the<br />

room for new parties to successfully<br />

establish themselves.<br />

Moser also noted that as a<br />

democracy matures, the number of parties<br />

would decrease. This is due to the fact that<br />

the political systems in gradually maturing<br />

democracies are moving towards the<br />

equilibrium number of political parties that<br />

it could support. In addition, this effect is<br />

especially prominent in new democracies,<br />

with parties converging at a higher rate than<br />

in more mature democracies. 14 Since Taiwan<br />

is a new democracy, having only fully<br />

granted citizens the rights to political<br />

participation in the early 1990’s, the<br />

movement towards a two-party system may<br />

simply be the course of party consolidation.<br />

Thus, the Taiwanese democracy’s growing<br />

maturity is also a factor in the reduction of<br />

the number of parties that are able to<br />

successfully get the candidates they fielded<br />

elected in the political system.<br />

Voter’s confusion of changing<br />

electoral rules might also be a factor in the<br />

observed strategic voting. Voters who split<br />

14 Ekaterina R Rashkova, “Political Learning, Legal<br />

Constraints and Party System Development: How do<br />

Party Law and Democratic Maturity Affect the<br />

Number of Parties?” The Legal Regulation of Political<br />

Parties Working Paper Series 5 (2010).<br />

their party and candidates votes could be<br />

doing so because they do not understand<br />

the relative importance of their ballots<br />

(Karp et al, 2002). 15 However, this<br />

explanation seems unsatisfactory. This is<br />

because Taiwan runs on an MMP system,<br />

whereas the literature of voter confusion is<br />

focused on the compensatory version of the<br />

mixed electoral system. 16 In an MMP<br />

system, the importance of each of the votes<br />

should be relatively clear to the voters,<br />

because the number of seats a party will<br />

receive for the PR portion of the legislature<br />

is completely separate from said party’s<br />

candidates’ performance in the constituent<br />

votes. Furthermore, it has been argued that<br />

split voting is actually a rational behavior<br />

whereby voters cast their ballots for<br />

candidates of different parties to attempt to<br />

maximize the effects of their votes, and that<br />

the voters know the implication of their<br />

actions. 17 During the past few years there have<br />

been many examples of prominent<br />

politicians from the “smaller” parties<br />

switching allegiance to the dominant party<br />

in their respective coalitions. For example,<br />

politicians from the People’s First Party,<br />

which originally split from the KMT, have<br />

been trickling back to the KMT since 2005.<br />

Shu-Lei Lo, Hung-Yuan Li, and former<br />

Taipei City mayor Shi-Wei Chou are all such<br />

examples. The smaller parties in the panblue<br />

coalition are not the only ones that<br />

suffered from the defection of their<br />

members. Yu-Yen Chien, originally from<br />

the Taiwan Solidarity Union, also defected<br />

to the DPP after falling out with the party<br />

leaders. The frequency of this kind of<br />

15 Jeffrey A. Karp et al, “Strategic Voting, Party<br />

Activity, and Candidate Effects: Testing<br />

Explanations for Split Voting in New Zealand’s New<br />

Mixed System,” Electoral Studies 21, no. 1 (2002): 1-22.<br />

16 Neal Jesse. “Falling into a Niche: Institutional<br />

Equilibrium Between Plurality and Proportional<br />

Representation for Large Political Parties.” Political<br />

Research Quarterly 51, no. 2 (1998): 481-503.<br />

17 Kathleen Bawn, “Voter Responses to Electoral<br />

Complexity: Ticket Splitting, Rational Voters and<br />

Representation in the Federal Republic of Germany,”<br />

British Journal of Political Science 29 (1999): 487-505.<br />

109 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 109


defections clearly illustrates the<br />

interchangeability of parties among parties<br />

in the same coalition, as mentioned before.<br />

Furthermore, it also encourages voters to<br />

further place their confidence and votes in<br />

the larger parties.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

The change from the SNTV<br />

electoral system to MMP has brought about<br />

a huge transformation in the Taiwanese<br />

political scene. The partisan tilt post-reform<br />

towards the KMT could be partially<br />

explained by the relative unpopularity of the<br />

DPP during the 2008 and the 2012 election<br />

cycles, just as the constriction of space for<br />

“small” party candidates vying for<br />

constituency seats could be adequately<br />

explained by Duverger’s Law. However,<br />

what could not be explained is the reduction<br />

of the number of small parties and the party<br />

seats they held in the Legislative Yuan, since<br />

all evidence of Duverger’s Law points to the<br />

decrease of strategic voting in a PR system.<br />

Throughout this essay some possible<br />

explanations for this deviation from the<br />

expected results have been offered. It seems<br />

that the political context of a nation does<br />

play an important role in shaping election<br />

outcomes, not just electoral rules. Hence,<br />

the unique pro-China and anti-China<br />

ideologies, the relative social homogeneity,<br />

and the growing maturity of the Taiwanese<br />

democracy all put constraints on the<br />

number of parties able to gain seats in the<br />

legislature. Furthermore, given the<br />

interchangeability of parties within the same<br />

coalition, many politicians switch<br />

allegiances. This also induces strategic<br />

voting behavior since similar policy stances<br />

across coalition parties reduce the cost for<br />

constituents to vote for a larger party over a<br />

smaller one. Thus, even a benign 5 percent<br />

of the total votes cast could become<br />

insurmountable for small party. This means<br />

that while electoral reform may have been<br />

able to solve the original problems of<br />

overabundance of party factions and<br />

extreme opinions, the reform comes with its<br />

own drawbacks. MMP system, or at least the<br />

version that Taiwan employs, is still unable<br />

to prevent strategic voting or provide equal<br />

opportunities for smaller parties to be<br />

represented in the legislature.<br />

PEI-YU WEI is a first year M.A. student in the<br />

Department of Politics concentrating in Political<br />

Economy. She graduated from the University of<br />

Hong Kong with a Bachelor's degree in Economics<br />

and Finance. Her articles have previously been<br />

published in The Diplomat and Apple Daily, Taiwan.<br />

She is currently an intern at the International Action<br />

Network on Small Arms.<br />

110 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 110


Empowering Women<br />

or Hollow Words?<br />

Gender References in Peace<br />

Agreements<br />

Lori Perkovich<br />

No country has yet to achieve gender<br />

equality, defined as equal rights and<br />

opportunity for men and women in<br />

all aspects of social, political and, economic<br />

life. The issue of gender is not solely a<br />

woman's matter, but rather involves the<br />

recognition of the diversity of both men<br />

and women. When women are excluded<br />

from decision-making and policies that<br />

involve their own welfare, the policies are<br />

often ineffective and inappropriate for<br />

women.<br />

The inclusion of women in peace<br />

processes is a crucial component to gender<br />

equality. It changes the discourse from<br />

viewing women primarily as victims to<br />

political actors and agents of change. The<br />

inclusion of explicit references to women,<br />

girls, and gender in peace agreements<br />

provides a tangible component in the<br />

furthering of women’s rights in conflictprone<br />

countries. These documents often<br />

function as de facto constitutions and,<br />

therefore, have the ability to pave the way<br />

for a new legal and political organization of<br />

state and society post-conflict. 1 It also<br />

creates a series of documents that<br />

governments must adhere to that can be<br />

monitored and researched by third party<br />

actors. Employing clear gender specific<br />

language for the inclusion of women in<br />

1 Christine Bell, “Peace Agreements: Their Nature<br />

and Legal Status,” American Journal of International<br />

Law, No. 100 (2006): 373–412, http://ssrn.com/<br />

abstract=1133550.<br />

political and legal structures, as well as<br />

equitable socio-economic provisions in<br />

peace agreements is the best way to ensure<br />

their future.<br />

Obtaining information regarding<br />

how many women participated in peace<br />

negotiations and evaluating the scope of<br />

their autonomy and authority still remains<br />

difficult. Examining the peace agreements<br />

and subsequent benchmark agreements can<br />

provide concrete, measurable indicators<br />

that are necessary to employ quantitative<br />

methods to describe the extent that gender<br />

equality is addressed and adhered to<br />

regarding women’s participation in the<br />

implementation and monitoring phase.<br />

Furthermore, it is possible to monitor the<br />

implementation process to understand if<br />

the mandates were either carried out or<br />

dismissed.<br />

LITERATURE REVIEW<br />

Historically, the inclusion of<br />

gender-responsive provisions in peace<br />

agreements ranks low on the list of<br />

conditions imposed by negotiating parties.<br />

Several scholars suggest that the obstacles<br />

to gender equality reforms in peace<br />

agreements stem from the fact that most<br />

negotiations happen in private, among men<br />

who are often focused on military<br />

concerns. Their primary concern demands<br />

the end of warfare and the establishment<br />

of power-sharing arrangements. 2<br />

In 2000, UNSC Resolution 1325<br />

mandated the “inclusion of women in the<br />

2 Christine Bell, C & O'Rourke, “Peace Agreements<br />

or Pieces of Paper: UN Security Council Resolution<br />

1325 and Peace Negotiations and Agreements,”<br />

Transitional Justice Institute Research Paper No. 11-01<br />

(March 2011), doi: 10.2139/ssrn.1781990;<br />

Chandra Lekha Sriram, “Making rights real?<br />

Minority and gender provisions and power-sharing<br />

arrangements,” The International Journal of Human<br />

Rights, No.17:2 (2013), doi:<br />

10.1080/13642987.2013.752947.<br />

111 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 111


prevention, management and resolution of<br />

conflict.” 3 This resolution was viewed by<br />

many as a game changer for women’s<br />

participation in peace processes. However,<br />

an alternative perspective posits Resolution<br />

1325 as “confused and confusing.” 4 Ellerby<br />

and Anderlini find the language<br />

problematic because all sections are open<br />

to interpretation and not clearly defined. 5<br />

Ellerby explains that historically,<br />

“prevention” meant prevention of war;<br />

whereas today, it is often used when<br />

discussing sexual and gender-based<br />

violence. This suggests that a standard of<br />

explicit definitions regarding the pillars of<br />

1325 is absent. 6<br />

The original research presented in<br />

this paper examines the scope of the<br />

references regarding women, girls, and<br />

gender in peace agreements from 2009 to<br />

2014 using quantitative and qualitative<br />

measures. A database was created to<br />

catalog and analyze gender language. Three<br />

categories were created in order to illustrate<br />

the quality of references and differentiate<br />

between easily implemented statements<br />

and those that will require further<br />

clarification. Qualitative measures were<br />

used in comparing two case studies: the<br />

Comprehensive Agreement on the<br />

Bangsamoro, Philippines (2014), and the<br />

Agreement Between the Government of<br />

3 Bell & O'Rourke (2011), “Peace Agreements or<br />

Pieces of Paper.”<br />

4 Kara Ellerby, “(En)gendered Security? The<br />

Complexities of Women's Inclusion in Peace<br />

Processes,” International Interactions: Empirical and<br />

Theoretical Research in International Relations, No. 39:4<br />

(2013): 435-460,<br />

doi:10.1080/03050629.2013.805327.<br />

5 Sanam Anderlini, “What the Women Say:<br />

Participation and UNSCR 1325,”<br />

MIT Center for International Studies, International Civil<br />

Society Action Network, (2010),<br />

http://web.mit.edu/cis/pdf/WomenReport_10_<br />

2010.pdf.<br />

6 Ellerby, “(En)gendered Security?”<br />

Sudan and The Justice and Equality<br />

Movement (JEM) –Sudan on The Basis of<br />

The Doha Document For Peace In Darfur<br />

and the JEM Ceasefire, Sudan (2013).<br />

SIGNIFICANCE OF GENDER<br />

LANGUAGE<br />

Why does gender language matter?<br />

Though references to gender or women do<br />

not necessarily indicate a “gender<br />

perspective” in a peace agreement, Bell and<br />

O’Rourke explain that it is not possible to<br />

have a gender perspective without the<br />

references to gender or women and doubt<br />

that these agreements will provide serious<br />

change for women without their active<br />

participation in the process. 7 Clear<br />

language is important because the<br />

mandates of ceasefires and peace accords<br />

establish the basis for peacebuilding plans<br />

such as monitoring, implementation and<br />

consequences for violations of the<br />

agreement. When agreements use vague<br />

gender language, such as “meaningful<br />

participation,” it leaves the intent of the<br />

directive open to interpretation. Moreover,<br />

if clear directives regarding women’s<br />

participation are not included, women will<br />

remain marginalized and excluded. It also<br />

paints an inaccurate picture that the<br />

negotiating parties are complying with<br />

international norms.<br />

QUOTAS TO ENSURE<br />

PARTICIPATION OF WOMEN IN<br />

POLITICS<br />

Bell and O’Rourke emphasize the<br />

importance of specifying a certain number<br />

of seats in government in peace<br />

7 Bell & O'Rourke (2011), “Peace Agreements or<br />

Pieces of Paper.”<br />

112 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 112


agreements. 8 In their research, they found<br />

that quotas in peace accords for female<br />

participation in politics are slowly on the<br />

rise, specifically with regard to indigenous<br />

women. For instance, in the negotiation of<br />

the Justice and Equality Movement (JEM)<br />

and the Sudan People’s Liberation<br />

Movement/Army (SPLM/A) peace<br />

agreements, specific allocations were made<br />

for Darfurian women to participate in the<br />

Sudanese government. 9<br />

While acknowledging the rise in<br />

provisions for quotas for women’s<br />

participation in government and an<br />

increase in access to political institutions,<br />

C. L. Sriram offers a less optimistic picture<br />

of approaches to female representation in<br />

peace agreements, including quotas. Sriram<br />

sites Democratic Republic of Congo’s<br />

Pretoria agreement (2002), which provided<br />

for “appropriate representation of women.” 10<br />

This type of generic language without a<br />

“set-aside” or mechanisms for<br />

implementation does not translate into<br />

tangible participation.<br />

Sriram also explains that when caps<br />

are attached to quotas, sometimes it creates<br />

barriers and limits participation<br />

opportunities. The Philippines Mindanao<br />

agreement (1996) included quotas but used<br />

a 15 percent cap. She suggests that quotas<br />

might not translate to legitimate<br />

participation or the creation of policies that<br />

bolster women’s rights because a position<br />

in government does not necessarily<br />

translate to legitimate participation or lead<br />

to changes regarding citizen’s rights. 11<br />

8 Christine Bell, & O'Rourke, “Peace Agreements or<br />

'Pieces of Paper?’ The Impact of UNSC Resolution<br />

1325 on Peace Processes and their Agreement<br />

International and Comparative,” Law Quarterly. No.<br />

59 (2010), last modified 08 August 2013, doi:<br />

954.10.1017/S002058931000062X.<br />

9 Bell & O'Rourke (2013), “Peace Agreements or<br />

Pieces of Paper.”<br />

10 Sriram, “Making rights real.”<br />

11 Ibid.<br />

UNITED NATIONS DATA ON<br />

GENDER LANGUAGE AND<br />

WOMEN’S PARTICIPATION<br />

The 2012 United Nations Security<br />

Council report offers statistics on recent<br />

inclusions of references in peace<br />

agreements to women, peace, and security.<br />

The report states that in 2010 and 2011, 22<br />

percent of signed peace agreements<br />

contained references to women, peace, and<br />

security, and 30 percent in 2012. 12 From 33<br />

peace negotiations in 2008, only 11 out of<br />

280 (4 percent) participants were women.<br />

“Participants” are defined as people<br />

assuming a range of roles, from advisors to<br />

witnesses. Among these, only 7 percent of<br />

negotiators were women. 13 From 1992 to<br />

2011, 9 percent out of a total 31 peace<br />

agreements had female negotiators. Eight<br />

countries had 4 percent female signatories<br />

and two had 2.4 percent female chief<br />

mediators. 14 Research from 2010 by Pablo<br />

Diaz confirms that women still struggle for<br />

a place at the negotiating table. 15<br />

Though research by Bell and<br />

O’Rourke shows an increase in gender<br />

references since Resolution 1325, the<br />

concern of the research in this paper is not<br />

solely the quantity of gender references but<br />

the quality of the language. Is it too vague?<br />

Do the gender references in agreements<br />

from 2009-2014 essentialize women by<br />

emphasizing the protection of women and<br />

girls instead of their participation in<br />

12 UN Fund for Women, Pablo Castillo Diaz, ed.,<br />

“Women’s Participation in Peace Negotiations:<br />

Connections Between Presence and Influence,” UN<br />

Fund for Women (August 2010) available from<br />

http://reliefweb.int/sites/reliefweb.int/files/resour<br />

ces/03AWomenPeaceNeg.pdf.<br />

13 Pablo Castillo Diaz, “Women’s Participation in<br />

Peace Negotiations.”<br />

14 Ibid.<br />

15 Ibid.<br />

113 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 113


negotiations and society? Or do these<br />

additions merely provide a hollow attempt<br />

at meeting international standards for<br />

women, peace, and security, but deliver no<br />

tangible substance? This new research<br />

investigates these gaps and identifies<br />

effective and inadequate practices.<br />

BACKGROUND, TABLES, AND<br />

FINDINGS<br />

In 2010, Professor Christine Bell<br />

and Dr. Catherine O’Rourke wrote the<br />

most comprehensive study on the inclusion<br />

of references to women and gender in<br />

peace agreements. The research analyzed<br />

585 documents between 1990 and 2010,<br />

399 of which were signed prior to<br />

Resolution 1325 and 186 after the<br />

resolution, as shown in Table 1. 16<br />

The catalog and subsequent<br />

analysis examine 145 documents, of which<br />

31 reference women and gender in peace<br />

agreements and ceasefires from 2009-2014.<br />

The data showed that 114 out of 145 (79<br />

percent) documents do not have any<br />

references to gender or female signatories.<br />

Of the 141 documents whose signatories’<br />

names were available, just 10 female had<br />

signed agreements that had gender<br />

reference; 22 female signatories were found<br />

in cases of agreements without any gender<br />

content. The catalog includes the type of<br />

reference, a description of the language and<br />

the section of the agreement where the<br />

language appears. The gender references<br />

were coded and 14 categories were created.<br />

Table 2 shows that 21 percent of<br />

the agreements include gender references:<br />

an increase of 5 percent from the 16<br />

percent found across 20 years of<br />

agreements in the Bell and O'Rourke study<br />

(1990-2010), but a decrease of 6 percent<br />

from the 27 percent of agreements with<br />

gender content in the specific nine-year<br />

period after the passage of UNSCR 1325 as<br />

reviewed by Bell and O'Rourke. Table 3<br />

offers the coding of the 14 categories for<br />

this study (2009-2014) and a total number<br />

of 133 gender references. Table 4 includes<br />

total number and percentage of specific<br />

references to women or gender issues<br />

(2009-2014) separated into three categories<br />

based on the type of mention.<br />

This study used three categories to<br />

describe the level and significance of the<br />

language used regarding references to<br />

women and gender.<br />

Category 1. Generic Blueprint reference:<br />

A statement that mentions a UNSC<br />

Resolution, CEDAW and other<br />

conferences on women and gender, or a<br />

generic gender reference.<br />

Category 2. Statement of Intent: Implies<br />

intent to take action on women’s<br />

participation or protection, using terms<br />

such as “meaningful” or “appropriate”<br />

participation, “equal and effective,<br />

adequate,” or “giving due consideration” to<br />

women’s needs, but these vague phrases<br />

are open to interpretation.<br />

Category 3. Specific Proposition/Quotas:<br />

A specific statement that is a clear policy<br />

directive and includes a percentage<br />

allocation for funding or quota provision<br />

for women’s representation in the peace<br />

process, or seats in government.<br />

16 Bell & O'Rourke, “Peace Agreements or 'Pieces<br />

of Paper?’”.<br />

114 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 114


QUANTITATIVE REVIEW OF GENDER REFERENCES IN PEACE<br />

AGREEMENTS<br />

Table 1: Peace agreement references women<br />

Peace agreements references<br />

to women<br />

Peace agreements references<br />

by percentage<br />

Before Resolution 1325 42 11%<br />

After Resolution 1325 50 27%<br />

Total 92 16%<br />

Professor Christine Bell and Dr. Catherine O’Rourke Data<br />

Table 2: Peace agreement references women<br />

Peace agreements references<br />

to women<br />

2009-2014 30 21%<br />

Author’s Data<br />

Peace agreements references<br />

by percentage<br />

Table 3: Individual references to women 2009-2014<br />

2014 2013<br />

Governance 0 Governance 6<br />

Quotas 0 Quotas 0<br />

General Development/ Education 0 General Development/ Education 3<br />

Women/Sexual Violence 1 Women/Sexual Violence 12<br />

Women Violence 1 Women Violence 1<br />

Girls in Conflict 0 Girls in Conflict 3<br />

Women Combatants 1 Women Combatants 2<br />

Advocate and Protect 0 Advocate and Protect 3<br />

Peace Process 0 Peace Process 4<br />

Motherhood 0 Motherhood 0<br />

Women/Girls 0 Women/Girls 1<br />

Socio-economic 1 Socio-economic 2<br />

UNSCR 1325/CEDAW/Beijing 0 UNSCR 1325/CEDAW/Beijing 3<br />

Platform<br />

Platform<br />

Prosecution/Legislation 0 Prosecution/Legislation 1<br />

Total: 4 Total: 41<br />

Author’s Data<br />

115 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 115


Table 3: Individual references to women 2009-2014<br />

2012 2011<br />

Governance 4 Governance 11<br />

Quotas 5 Quotas 9<br />

General Development/ Education 2 General Development/ Education 7<br />

Women/Sexual Violence 1 Women/Sexual Violence 3<br />

Women Violence 0 Women Violence 2<br />

Girls in Conflict 0 Girls in Conflict 5<br />

Women Combatants 0 Women Combatants 1<br />

Advocate and Protect 0 Advocate and Protect 4<br />

Peace Process 0 Peace Process 5<br />

Motherhood 0 Motherhood 1<br />

Women/Girls 4 Women/Girls 7<br />

Socio-economic 0 Socio-economic 6<br />

UNSCR 1325/CEDAW/Beijing 0 UNSCR 1325/CEDAW/Beijing 1<br />

Platform<br />

Platform<br />

Prosecution/Legislation 0 Prosecution/Legislation 2<br />

Total: 16 Total: 64<br />

Author’s Data<br />

2010 2009<br />

Governance 1 Governance 0<br />

Quotas 0 Quotas 0<br />

General Development/ Education 0 General Development/ Education 0<br />

Women/Sexual Violence 0 Women/Sexual Violence 0<br />

Women Violence 1 Women Violence 0<br />

Girls in Conflict 2 Girls in Conflict 0<br />

Women Combatants 0 Women Combatants 0<br />

Advocate and Protect 0 Advocate and Protect 0<br />

Peace Process 0 Peace Process 0<br />

Motherhood 0 Motherhood 0<br />

Women/Girls 1 Women/Girls 0<br />

Socio-economic 0 Socio-economic 2<br />

UNSCR 1325/CEDAW/Beijing 0 UNSCR 1325/CEDAW/Beijing 0<br />

Platform<br />

Platform<br />

Prosecution/Legislation 1 Prosecution/Legislation 0<br />

Total: 6 Total: 2<br />

Author’s Data<br />

116 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 116


Table 4: Individual references to women 2009-2014<br />

Categories of Women and Gender Reference in 2014<br />

1. Generic Blueprint 2. Statement of 3. Specific<br />

Total<br />

Intent Proposition/Quotas<br />

0 4 0 4<br />

Categories of Women and Gender Reference in 2013<br />

1. Generic Blueprint 2. Statement of 3. Specific<br />

Total<br />

Intent Proposition/Quotas<br />

8 17 16 41<br />

Categories of Women and Gender Reference in 2012<br />

1. Generic Blueprint 2. Statement of 3. Specific<br />

Total<br />

Intent Proposition/Quotas<br />

3 7 6 16<br />

Categories of Women and Gender Reference in 2011<br />

1. Generic Blueprint 2. Statement of 3. Specific<br />

Total<br />

Intent Proposition/Quotas<br />

5 46 13 64<br />

Categories of Women and Gender Reference in 2010<br />

1. Generic Blueprint 2. Statement of 3. Specific<br />

Total<br />

Intent Proposition/Quotas<br />

1 5 0 6<br />

Categories of Women and Gender Reference in 2009<br />

1. Generic Blueprint 2. Statement of 3. Specific<br />

Total<br />

Intent Proposition/Quotas<br />

1 0 1 2<br />

Author’s Data<br />

Categories of Women and Gender Reference<br />

Total Number<br />

Percentage<br />

1. Generic Blueprint 18 14%<br />

2. Statement of Intent 79 59%<br />

3. Specific<br />

36 27%<br />

Proposition/Quotas<br />

Total: 133<br />

Author’s Data<br />

117 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 117


A review of Table 3 shows that<br />

from 2009-2014, the highest numbers of<br />

gender references are found in agreements<br />

signed during 2011, 2012, and 2013. The<br />

numbers are well dispersed among most of<br />

the categories with 64 gender mentions in<br />

2011 and 41 in 2013. However, the 16<br />

references in 2012 occur in the categories<br />

of governance, quotas, general<br />

development and education, women and<br />

sexual violence, and women and girls. In<br />

2009, there are two references that pertain<br />

solely to socio-economic issues, and in<br />

2010, six mentions are spread among the<br />

categories of governance, prosecution and<br />

legislation, violence against women, girls in<br />

conflict and women and girls. In 2014, four<br />

references appear in the categories of<br />

women and sexual violence, violence<br />

against women, women combatants, and<br />

socio-economics. The highest numbers of<br />

references occur from 2011 to 2013. The<br />

table depicts 2014 as the lowest number of<br />

references since 2009.<br />

Table 4 explains the significance of<br />

the gender references for each year. Most<br />

of the references occur in category two or<br />

three, which implies intent and specificity.<br />

The references in years 2011 and 2013 are<br />

in categories that provide specific directives<br />

or quotas that are easily implemented and<br />

are not open to interpretation. These types<br />

of references have the most bearing on the<br />

lives of women. In 2011, 46 statement of<br />

intent references and 13 specific<br />

propositions or quotas were included in<br />

agreements; 17 statement of intent<br />

references and 16 specific propositions or<br />

quotas appeared in 2013.<br />

The inclusion of statements of<br />

intent is significant because most peace<br />

agreements use vague language, which<br />

leads to misinterpretation of the directive.<br />

The use of statements of intent and quotas<br />

indicates a commitment to implement<br />

gender equality mandates. These references<br />

also move beyond standard protection<br />

recommendations and provide specific<br />

allocations for money, services, and set<br />

numbers (quotas) of government positions<br />

for women.<br />

CASE STUDIES<br />

The Comprehensive Agreement on the Bangsamoro<br />

(2014), Philippines<br />

Progressive gender provisions<br />

The Comprehensive Agreement on<br />

the Bangsamoro (2014) empowers women<br />

through significant provisions regarding<br />

socioeconomics, political positions,<br />

decommissioned females officers, security,<br />

and policing. The Annex on Revenue<br />

Generation and Wealth Sharing offers the<br />

most specific example of funding for<br />

women in section “XII. Gender and<br />

Development.” It stipulates that 5 percent<br />

of official public development funds must<br />

be allocated “for support programs and<br />

activities for women in accordance with a<br />

gender and development plan.” 17<br />

The Annex on Normalization<br />

(2014) provides socio-economic programs<br />

for decommissioned female officers of The<br />

Moro Islamic Liberation Front (MILF). 18<br />

The inclusion of economic provisions for<br />

decommissioned female officers is<br />

significant because women are often<br />

excluded from benefits in disarmament,<br />

demobilization, and reintegration (DDR)<br />

processes. Furthermore, while DDR<br />

17 UN Peacemaker, “Philippines, State Annex on<br />

Revenue Generation and Wealth-sharing to the<br />

Framework Agreement on the Bangsamoro (FAB),”<br />

(13 July 2013), available from<br />

peacemaker.un.org/philippines-annexwealthsharing2013.<br />

18 UN Peacemaker, Annex on Normalization to the<br />

Framework Agreement on the Bangsamoro (FAB),<br />

(January 2014), available from<br />

peacemaker.un.org/philippines-annexnormalization2014.<br />

118 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 118


programs do include women, they often do<br />

not differentiate in their provisions for<br />

men and women. This can be problematic<br />

in situations where women would receive<br />

cash yet are not allowed to have access to<br />

money in their household.<br />

Generic language and matters of concern<br />

The Annex on Power-Sharing<br />

(FAB) (2013) includes numerous<br />

provisions for women in government. For<br />

instance, to ensure women’s participation,<br />

one provision states that in accordance<br />

with basic Bangsamoro law, women must<br />

participate in government, but specific<br />

minimum percentages are not indicated. 19<br />

The document also stipulates that the<br />

Bangsamoro Council of Leaders,comprised<br />

of governors, mayors, one member of each<br />

indigenous community, and chaired by the<br />

Deputy Chief Minister, must include a<br />

female representative. 20 The agreement also<br />

uses imprecise language such as<br />

“establishment of appropriate mechanisms<br />

for consultations for women” and “special<br />

development programs and laws for<br />

women,” but does not describe the<br />

mechanism for achieving these<br />

consultations, nor the specific type of<br />

programs or laws envisaged.<br />

Although sections of the peace<br />

agreement make detailed references to<br />

females in policing, women are not<br />

mentioned in the policing section of the<br />

Annex on Normalization. 21 This is a missed<br />

opportunity to include women in the<br />

implementation, resolution, and<br />

monitoring phases of the peace process.<br />

Female police officers help in decreasing<br />

19 UN Peacemaker, Annex on Power-Sharing to the<br />

Framework Agreement on the Bangsamoro (FAB),<br />

(December 2013), available from<br />

peacemaker.un.org/philippines-annexpowersharing2013.<br />

20 UN Peacemaker, Annex on Power-Sharing.<br />

21 UN Peacemaker, Annex on Normalization.<br />

women’s fear to report crimes and improve<br />

responses to domestic and sexual violence,<br />

which are prevalent crimes post-conflict.<br />

However this was not made a requirement.<br />

Both the GPH-MILF Decision Points on<br />

Principles as of April 2012 and the<br />

Framework Agreement on the Bangsamoro<br />

15th October 2012 address the rights of<br />

women and specify “protection from<br />

violence.” 22 These statements call for the<br />

protection of women but they do not<br />

prescribe punishment for those who cause<br />

harm to women. In order to prevent<br />

violence against women, there must be<br />

justice for victims and an end to impunity.<br />

This process should also include<br />

consultations with women to determine<br />

priorities for justice initiatives. Justice is a<br />

necessary component for recognizing past<br />

abuses in order to build public confidence<br />

going forward and prevent future conflict.<br />

Also of concern are some aspects of the<br />

provisions for future justice options in the<br />

Annex on Power Sharing and Framework<br />

Agreement. Their references to Sharia law<br />

and customary justice leave the door open<br />

to the use of Sharia Law to solve disputes<br />

that would typically be heard in the judicial<br />

system. Because of the limited rights of<br />

women under Sharia law, it does not bode<br />

well for women. 23<br />

Agreement Between the Government of Sudan and<br />

The Justice and Equality Movement-Sudan on<br />

The Basis of The Doha Document For Peace In<br />

Darfur Sudan; and Sudan Ceasefire JEM<br />

(2013), Sudan<br />

The 2013 Sudanese peace process<br />

featured three documents: the Agreement<br />

Between the Government of Sudan and<br />

The Justice and Equality Movement-Sudan<br />

on The Basis of The Doha Document For<br />

Peace In Darfur Sudan; Sudan Ceasefire<br />

22 UN Peacemaker, Philippines GPH-MILF (2012).<br />

23 UN Peacemaker, Annex on Power-Sharing.<br />

119 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 119


JEM (2013); and Protocol on the<br />

Participation of JEM-Sudan at the different<br />

levels of Government and on the<br />

Integration of its Forces. The latter does<br />

not include any references to women or<br />

gender.<br />

Progressive gender provisions<br />

Gender references in the Sudan<br />

peace agreement and ceasefire focus mainly<br />

on security of women, exploitation of girls<br />

and women’s involvement in the peace<br />

process. However, there is a progressive<br />

provision for the empowerment of<br />

Nomadic women that specifies that<br />

nomadic women must receive education. 24<br />

The clause also states that a Social Welfare<br />

Fund (DRA) with provisions for women<br />

must be created and the fund must be a<br />

minimum of 50 million US dollars. 25<br />

In the Sudan Ceasefire JEM (2013),<br />

specific language is used referencing the<br />

establishment of sub-units that must<br />

include women during the monitoring<br />

phase as a means to report on issues and<br />

violations ceasefire. 26 The document<br />

specifies that all issues regarding violence<br />

against women must be heard in a “gender<br />

sensitive and competent manner,” which<br />

does identify one of the constraints<br />

associated with interviewing women. 27<br />

Generic language and matters of concern<br />

24 UN Peacemaker, Protocol on the Participation of<br />

JEM-Sudan at the different levels of Government and on the<br />

Integration of its Forces, (March 2013), available at<br />

available at peacemaker.un.org/sudan-protocolparticipation-jems2013.<br />

25 UN Peacemaker, Protocol on the Participation of<br />

JEM-Sudan.<br />

26 UN Peacemaker, Ceasefire Agreement between the<br />

Government of Sudan and the Justice and Equality<br />

Movement-Sudan (JEM), (February 2013) available at<br />

peacemaker.un.org/sudan-ceasefire-jems2013.<br />

27 UN Peacemaker, Sudan Ceasefire Agreement.<br />

The Sudanese agreement raises<br />

cause for concern in areas where general<br />

phrases are used regarding the role of<br />

women in peacemaking and violence<br />

against women. Additional areas of<br />

concern are the absence of references to<br />

women in sections of the document that<br />

determine participation in government and<br />

participation of girls and women in militias,<br />

and their subsequent demobilization.<br />

The Ceasefire guarantees women<br />

the right to protection. It states that<br />

“specific measures for vulnerable groups<br />

such as women” will be created but does<br />

not explain the measures. Instead of<br />

providing specific details, the document<br />

makes sweeping and generic references<br />

such as, “facilitate the UNAMID mandate<br />

UNSCR 1935.” 28 Phrases such as “Refrain<br />

from all acts of violence” against women<br />

and “gender-based violence and sexual<br />

exploitation” are also used. 29 These<br />

statements describe violent crimes against<br />

women but do not stipulate the penalties<br />

for violating the terms of the agreement.<br />

With regard to the militias and<br />

children, a blueprint statement explains<br />

that recruitment of boys and girls under 18<br />

is not allowed, and is a violation of the<br />

1949 Geneva Conventions. 30 All armed<br />

forces must comply with implementation<br />

of the agreement that calls for the release<br />

of women and girls under “control or<br />

influence” of the military. Communication<br />

regarding their release must be passed<br />

through the chain of command to all<br />

armed forces and unconditional release of<br />

girls from the armed forces is mandatory<br />

through the national action plans. The<br />

plans provide the institutional framework<br />

necessary to implement and monitor peace<br />

agreement provisions. Moreover, it states<br />

that girls are to be treated as victims, not<br />

28 Ibid.<br />

29 Ibid.<br />

30 Ibid.<br />

120 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 120


perpetrators. Though the language is<br />

allocation of positions during various<br />

descriptive, the details for implementation stages of the peace process, such as<br />

are vague. 31<br />

negotiations, security, implementation, and<br />

monitoring, as well as in determining<br />

Table 5: Categories of women and<br />

government positions. With regard to<br />

gender references<br />

participation in the peace process, both<br />

processes featured women in the<br />

Philippines 2014 Sudan 2013<br />

negotiations, though the extent of their<br />

1. Generic Blueprint 0 5<br />

participation and influence is extremely<br />

2. Statement of Intent 10 6<br />

difficult to ascertain without field research,<br />

3. Specific Provisions/ 5 4<br />

and is therefore beyond the scope of this<br />

Quotas<br />

study.<br />

Total Gender Mentions 15 15<br />

Author’s Data 32<br />

The Philippines agreement is<br />

evenly balanced with regard to the type of<br />

inclusions of women and gender, such as<br />

government, peace process, security, and<br />

socio-economics. The Sudanese<br />

agreements focus primarily on security of<br />

women, gender-based violence, and<br />

provisions for limited participation in the<br />

peace process. Both agreements do a good<br />

job of explaining where women should be<br />

included in the implementation process<br />

post-conflict. The documents often detail<br />

the types of resources that should be<br />

provided for them, but in some cases the<br />

specifics on the minimum numbers of seats<br />

for women in political assemblies or<br />

minimum public resources for allocation to<br />

services to address women’s needs remain<br />

the missing link between policy documents<br />

and implementation. Women should also<br />

have specific consideration--separate from<br />

indigenous individuals—regarding<br />

31 UN Peacemaker, Sudan Ceasefire Agreement.<br />

32 The Comprehensive Agreement on the<br />

Bangsamoro (2014), Philippines included one<br />

mention of UNSCR 1325 but it was attached to<br />

a statement counted in category number 2 and<br />

therefore not counted in category 1 for the<br />

purposes of this study.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

The inclusion of references to<br />

women and gender in peace agreements is<br />

important for women’s rights, but it is not<br />

just quantity that matters. Quality and the<br />

use of precise language are even more<br />

crucial to make sure action is taken. There<br />

needs to be a move away from using<br />

language such as “meaningful<br />

participation” because it often cannot be<br />

implemented. Without further explanation<br />

and without clear provisions, there is a risk<br />

that obstacles such as culture, poverty, lack<br />

of education, and patriarchy will block<br />

women from achieving their goals.<br />

This study shows a slight increase<br />

in gender references of 5 percent of<br />

agreements from the 16 percent in the Bell<br />

and O'Rourke study. More importantly, it<br />

is promising that the majority of the<br />

references fell in categories that showed an<br />

increase in either intent or direct action in<br />

commitment to the empowerment of<br />

women. Although the two case studies are<br />

two of the best examples of progressive<br />

gender language between 2009-2014, there<br />

is still room for improvement.<br />

While this study offers a<br />

foundation for assessing recent gender<br />

language and also a review of signatories of<br />

peace agreements, there are still areas of<br />

the peacemaking process that require<br />

121 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 121


further research. The level of difficulty in<br />

acquiring information regarding female<br />

participation such as gender experts,<br />

women negotiators, and women’s<br />

organizations proved to be an obstacle in<br />

producing a more complete picture of the<br />

involvement of women. However, the<br />

findings in this study show that gender<br />

language in peace agreements is evolving in<br />

a positive manner but at a slower pace than<br />

desired.<br />

Too much emphasis remains on<br />

portraying and making provisions for<br />

women as victims instead of as actors with<br />

decision-making power. Peace agreements<br />

lay the groundwork for future societies by<br />

providing directives regarding socioeconomics,<br />

funding, quotas for<br />

employment, and also the creation of new<br />

legislation. By addressing gender<br />

inequalities in the aforementioned areas,<br />

many of the obstacles that women face will<br />

be removed. The language employed in<br />

peace agreements determines whether<br />

women are recognized and respected, or<br />

whether they will remain discriminated<br />

against.<br />

LORI PERKOVICH previously worked as a<br />

communications manager. In May <strong>2015</strong>, she<br />

finishes her Master of Science in Global Affairs<br />

at New York University (NYU) SPS with a<br />

concentration in International Relations, and a<br />

Gender Specialization. Her geo-political<br />

interests focus on Africa and much of her<br />

research at NYU has centered on conflict and<br />

peacebuilding; women, peace and security.<br />

Currently, she is a research and advocacy<br />

consultant for the Global Network of Women<br />

Peacebuilders (GNWP).<br />

122 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 122


A New Cold War in the<br />

Arctic?<br />

Roma Parhad<br />

It is easy to think of the Arctic region as<br />

pristine and peaceful. However, recent<br />

scientific predictions and military buildup<br />

require further scrutiny. Accelerated ice<br />

melt has made Arctic resources more<br />

accessible to the countries encircling the<br />

North Pole. As a result, Russia has increased<br />

military and exploratory activity in the region.<br />

Russia’s heavy dependence on hydrocarbons,<br />

Arctic military build-up, and newly aggressive<br />

foreign policy forecasts a potential threat to<br />

the United States, its interests, and its allies in<br />

the Arctic north. Russia’s stated goal of<br />

resurrecting its great power status and desire<br />

to balance against the United States drives<br />

Moscow’s foreign policy, including its Arctic<br />

intentions. 1 However, Western-imposed<br />

sanctions against Russia over its involvement<br />

in the ongoing Ukrainian Crisis are changing<br />

the outlook for the far north, requiring an<br />

assessment of Russian intentions and<br />

capabilities with regards to U.S. national<br />

security. This assessment analyzes Russia’s<br />

capabilities and intentions under the<br />

remainder of President Vladimir Putin’s term<br />

until 2018.<br />

Understanding Russia’s capabilities<br />

and intentions requires an assessment of<br />

Russian hydrocarbon dependence, national<br />

aspirations, legal claims, economic capacity,<br />

military strength, geography, and<br />

environmental limitations. It is highly likely<br />

1 Michael L. Roi, “Russia: The Greatest Arctic Power?”<br />

Journal of Slavic Military Studies 23, (2010): 559.<br />

that Russia intends to continue its military<br />

build-up in the Arctic, specifically its nuclear<br />

deterrence capabilities. Its primary reasons for<br />

doing so include the desire to restore its status<br />

as a world power, to have access to vital<br />

resources, and to defend its borders and<br />

regional interests from perceived threats by<br />

other nations. However, Russian capabilities<br />

in the Arctic will likely not match its<br />

intentions for at least the next three years.<br />

Moscow’s current activities in the region will<br />

not be a significant threat to the United States<br />

and its allies.<br />

THE ARCTIC REGION<br />

The Arctic is expected to hold nearly a<br />

quarter of the Earth’s undiscovered but<br />

recoverable oil and natural gas; more than<br />

80% of these reserves are expected to be<br />

offshore. 2 The Arctic seabed may also contain<br />

significant deposits of valuable metals and<br />

precious stones. 3 Accessibility to the region, to<br />

a “Northwest Passage” across the Arctic<br />

Circle, is increasing because the region is<br />

warming at twice the rate of the rest of the<br />

planet. Some scientists forecast ice-free Arctic<br />

summers in the coming decades. 4 The fastpaced<br />

warming highlights the region’s<br />

potential, as ice-melt leads to easier access to<br />

underwater natural resources, new fishing<br />

grounds, and new shipping routes between<br />

the Pacific and Atlantic that may cut sea travel<br />

2 “The Emerging Arctic.” Council on Foreign Relations,<br />

accessed on November 10, 2014.<br />

http://www.cfr.org/arctic/emerging-arctic/p32620#!/<br />

3 Stephen J. Blank, ed. “Russia in the Arctic,” Strategic<br />

Studies Institute, July 2011: 4, accessed on November<br />

11, 2014.<br />

http://www.strategicstudiesinstitute.army.mil/pdffiles/<br />

PUB1073.pdf<br />

4 Kathrin Keil, “The Arctic: A New Region of Conflict?<br />

The Case of Oil and Gas,” Cooperation and Conflict, June<br />

6, 2013, 162.<br />

123 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 123


time by up to 40%. 5 Given how recent the<br />

emergence of the Arctic’s resource wealth is,<br />

the region has historically not been a core U.S.<br />

interest due to its harsh climate and the high<br />

cost of technologies required to overcome<br />

these obstacles. 6 It plays a minor role in U.S.<br />

national defense policy, though during the<br />

Cold War, NATO sites in Greenland, Canada,<br />

and Alaska were part of the U.S.’s early<br />

warning and first strike nuclear capabilities. 7<br />

Thus far, the Arctic has remained a<br />

surprisingly peaceful and collaborative region.<br />

The five littoral Arctic powers—Russia,<br />

Norway, Denmark (Greenland), Canada, and<br />

the United States—joined Sweden, Finland,<br />

and Iceland to create the Arctic Council in<br />

1996. Its mission is to support environmental<br />

protection and sustainable development in the<br />

region, but does not address military security<br />

issues. 8 The North Atlantic Treaty<br />

Organization (NATO) has an important role<br />

in the region since four of the “Arctic Five”<br />

and five of the eight countries in the Arctic<br />

Council are member states. Russia, the only<br />

non-NATO littoral state, has committed to<br />

following the United Nations Convention on<br />

the Laws of the Sea (UNCLOS) guidelines for<br />

its claims in the Arctic. UNCLOS allows<br />

states to petition for ownership of resources<br />

in a specific area if they can prove their<br />

continental shelf extends past the average 200<br />

nautical miles granted to nations. The United<br />

States has not ratified UNCLOS, although it<br />

recognizes most components of it under<br />

international law. If the U.N. recognizes<br />

5 “Arctic Transit: Northern Sea Route,” Royal Belgian<br />

Institute of Marine Engineers, Issue 4, 2012: 1,<br />

accessed November 23, 2014.<br />

http://www.gallois.be/ggmagazine_2013/gg_02_03_2<br />

013_90.pdf<br />

6 Zdeněk Kříž and Filip Chrášťanský, “Existing<br />

Conflicts in the Arctic and the Risk of Escalation:<br />

Rhetoric and Reality,” Perspectives 20, no.1 (2012): 113.<br />

7 Lauren Goodrich and Marc Lanthemann, “The Past,<br />

Present and Future of Russian Energy Strategy,”<br />

STRATFOR Global Intelligence, February 12, 2013.<br />

8 “The Emerging Arctic”<br />

Russia’s claims in the Arctic, this will stand in<br />

opposition to U.S. interests in the region,<br />

namely freedom of the seas and navigation to<br />

prevent one power from gaining exclusive<br />

control over an area of the ocean. 9<br />

RUSSIAN INTENTIONS IN THE<br />

ARCTIC<br />

Russia’s increased exploration in the<br />

Arctic, resumption of Cold War era bomber<br />

patrols, regional military buildup, and political<br />

posturing are cause for concern as indicators<br />

of Russian intentions and capabilities in the<br />

region. 10 However, these intentions are not<br />

offensive in nature; rather, they are grounded<br />

in hydrocarbon dependence, national status<br />

implications, and a desire to assert legal rights.<br />

The primary motivation for Arctic<br />

involvement is the Russian economy’s<br />

substantial dependence on hydrocarbons, a<br />

significant amount of which comes from<br />

north of the Arctic Circle in. 11 Oil and gas<br />

revenues account for more than 50% of<br />

Russia’s federal budget revenue and 68% of<br />

exports. 12 The high dependence on<br />

hydrocarbon revenue has resulted in the ruble<br />

being pegged to the price of oil. As gas prices<br />

drop so too does the value of the ruble,<br />

weakening the Russian economy. 13 The<br />

official Russian Arctic strategy, released in<br />

9 The National Security Strategy for the Arctic Region, The<br />

White House, May 2013, accessed December 1, 2014.<br />

https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/docs<br />

/nat_arctic_strategy.pdf<br />

10 Paal Sigurd Hilde, “The ‘new’ Arctic—the Military<br />

Dimension,” Journal of Military and Strategic Studies 15,<br />

no. 2 (2013): 134.<br />

11 Blank, ed. “Russia in the Arctic,” 116.<br />

12 “Russia,” U.S. Energy Information Administration,<br />

March 12, 2014, accessed on November 29, 2014.<br />

http://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/index.cfm?tg=natu<br />

ral%20gas<br />

13 Natalie Kitroeff and Joseph Weisenthal, “Here’s Why<br />

the Russian Ruble is Collapsing,” Bloomberg Business<br />

News, 16 December 16, 2014, accessed on April 20,<br />

<strong>2015</strong>. http://www.bloomberg.com/bw/articles/2014-<br />

12-16/no-caviar-is-not-getting-cheaper-everything-youneed-to-know-about-the-russian-ruble-collapse<br />

124 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 124


2008, sees the region as a national strategic<br />

resource base that is essential to its<br />

socioeconomic ability to grow, and it’s<br />

standing in the international community. 14<br />

Moscow’s goal is to make the Arctic its<br />

leading energy resource base by 2020. 15 This is<br />

due, in part, to the main hub of Russian oil<br />

production, in West Siberian petroleum basin,<br />

getting closer to reaching peak output, barring<br />

investment or improved equipment. 16 Even<br />

with such technologies, there is concern over<br />

how long reserves will last in a region that has<br />

been heavily exploited for several decades. 17<br />

Russia’s access to energy resources is<br />

synonymous with its ability to influence<br />

foreign and domestic policy. 18 But due to<br />

limited capabilities to affordably access these<br />

resources, interest in Arctic hydrocarbons will<br />

not result in aggressive Russian action.<br />

Russia views nuclear deterrence and<br />

access to resources as the keys to reviving its<br />

great power status. 19 Maintaining its vision of<br />

being the greatest Arctic power is one of the<br />

driving forces behind an Arctic military buildup.<br />

The Arctic is where Russia’s defense<br />

capabilities and security must be ensured in<br />

the coming decades. 20 For Russia, the battle<br />

for resources is synonymous with the battle<br />

for sovereignty and its ability to influence<br />

foreign and domestic policy. 21 Although<br />

Russia has acted cooperatively in the region to<br />

date, the use of military force to resolve these<br />

issues has not been ruled out in the<br />

government’s strategy. 22 Drawing on its<br />

historical connection to the Arctic and strong<br />

frontier myths, 23 the issue is ideological as well<br />

as strategic. 24 Russian history has in recent<br />

years become an increasingly important<br />

rhetorical theme found in justifications for<br />

Russian foreign policy, from the Georgian<br />

conflict in 2008 to the ongoing crisis in<br />

Ukraine and annexation of the Crimea.<br />

Russia argues it possesses a legitimate<br />

claim to a significant quantity of resources in<br />

the Arctic region. Some of the claims cross<br />

into international waters, and Russia’s<br />

intention to charge a transportation fee for<br />

this route violates the concept of freedom of<br />

the seas. 25 According to Russian accounts, a<br />

new bid for these claims will be placed with<br />

the U.N. in the spring of <strong>2015</strong>, though<br />

currently, the bid is far behind the original<br />

schedule. 26 If Russia does gain access to these<br />

areas, in addition to significant resource<br />

wealth, it would have the Northern Sea Route<br />

at its disposal, which would give it control of<br />

the shortest maritime route from North<br />

America to Europe to Asia. 27 However, given<br />

the U.N. committee’s heavy backlog it is not<br />

likely to rule on the claims before 2018. 28<br />

14 Keil, “The Arctic: A New Region of Conflict?”<br />

166-7.<br />

15 Blank, ed. “Russia in the Arctic,” 18.<br />

16 Melissa Renee Pegna. “U.S Artic Policy: The Need to<br />

Ratify a Modified UNCLOS and Secure a Military<br />

Presence in the Arctic,” Journal of Maritime Law &<br />

Commerce 44, no. 2, April 2013, 179-180.<br />

17 Blank, ed. “Russia in the Arctic,” 106.<br />

18 “Arctic Resources: The Fight for the Coldest Place<br />

on Earth Heats Up.” RT, April 15, 2014, accessed on<br />

November 15, 2014. http://rt.com/news/arcticreclamation-resources-race-524/<br />

19 Goodrich and Lanthemann, “The Past, Present and<br />

Future of Russian Energy Strategy,”<br />

20 Todd L. Sharp. “The Implications of Ice Melt on<br />

Arctic Security,” Defence Studies 11, no. 2 (2011): 304.<br />

21 “Arctic Resources: The Fight for the Coldest Place<br />

on Earth Heats Up.”<br />

22 Blank, ed. “Russia in the Arctic,” 20.<br />

23 Politics: Too Much to Fight Over,” The Economist,<br />

June 16, 2012, accessed on December 1, 2014.<br />

http://www.economist.com/node/21556797<br />

24 Kříž and Chrášťanský. “Existing Conflicts in the<br />

Arctic and the Risk of Escalation,” 133.<br />

25 Blank, ed. “Russia in the Arctic,” 26.<br />

26 Tom Parfitt, “Russia Lays Claims to Billions of Tons<br />

of Arctic Oil and Gas,” The Telegraph, October 31, 2014,<br />

accessed April 20, <strong>2015</strong>.<br />

http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/worldnews/europe<br />

/russia/11199323/Russia-lays-claim-to-billions-oftons-of-Arctic-oil-and-gas.html<br />

27 Blank, ed., “Russia in the Arctic,” 48.<br />

28 Sharp, “The Implications of Ice Melt on Arctic<br />

Security,” 314.<br />

125 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 125


RUSSIAN CAPABILITIES IN THE<br />

ARCTIC<br />

Russia’s intentions to increase its<br />

presence in the Arctic are frustrated by its<br />

limited capabilities to project its power there,<br />

militarily or otherwise. 29 Russian Arctic<br />

capabilities are unlikely to develop due to<br />

Russia’s poor economy, outdated Arctic<br />

military, and other environmental barriers.<br />

However, from these examples, Russia’s<br />

faltering economy is the primary reason it will<br />

not be able to achieve its Arctic plans by<br />

2018. As a result of recent sanctions on Russia<br />

over the Ukrainian Crisis, high-tech projects<br />

have been put on hold, including joint<br />

ventures with Western companies in the<br />

region. 30 Falling world gas prices and a<br />

shrinking market will also have a negative<br />

impact on Russian energy projects. 31 Due to<br />

the uncertainty of the direction of the gas<br />

market, Russia has put several large gas<br />

exploitation projects on hold—citing high<br />

costs and low prices. 32 The Russian oil<br />

company Rosneft has reportedly asked the<br />

government for more than US$40 billion<br />

dollars to offset losses due to sanctions. 33<br />

This loss of foreign assistance will be<br />

especially felt in the Arctic. Oil and gas<br />

production there involve high capital and<br />

29 Pegna. “U.S Artic Policy,” 180.<br />

30 Olga Ivshina, “Russian Oil Industry Facing a Deep<br />

Freeze,” BBC News, November 26, 2014, accessed on<br />

April 20, <strong>2015</strong>. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/worldeurope-30217070<br />

31 Paul Roderick Gregory, “Western Sanctions and<br />

Rising Debts Are Already Strangling the Russian<br />

Economy,” Forbes, August 28, 2014, accessed on April<br />

20, <strong>2015</strong>.<br />

http://www.forbes.com/sites/paulroderickgregory/20<br />

14/08/28/western-sanctions-and-rising-debts-arealready-strangling-the-russian-economy/.<br />

32 “The Emerging Arctic.”<br />

33 Vauhini Vara. “Hurt Putin, Hurt Yourself?” The New<br />

Yorker, August 19, 2014, accessed on December 2,<br />

<strong>2015</strong>.<br />

http://www.newyorker.com/business/currency/hurtputin-hurt<br />

operating costs for building infrastructure and<br />

getting the product to market. 34 Russia is<br />

predicted to lose significant amounts of<br />

foreign direct investment by the end of <strong>2015</strong>,<br />

including much technology and managerial<br />

know-how that it desperately needs for its oil<br />

and gas industries. 35 Attempts to develop and<br />

replace Western technology to circumvent the<br />

sanctions will take at least several years. 36 High<br />

operating costs in the Arctic and the profit<br />

motive 37 to develop their own undisputed<br />

resources rather than fight over resources they<br />

do not have access to, are indicators that<br />

Russia is likely to continue with peaceful<br />

exploration of the region for the next few<br />

years. 38 Additionally, Russia’s military<br />

capabilities in the Arctic are not robust<br />

enough to be a threat to U.S. national security<br />

for several years to come. Even though the<br />

Russian strategy defines the Arctic as Russia’s<br />

most important arena for international and<br />

military security and claims that its ability to<br />

defend its national security is contingent on<br />

the country’s economic potential, the<br />

infrastructure is not present. 39 Russia has<br />

identified problems in the form of easy access<br />

to the region by other nations, a shortage of<br />

34 “U.S. Navy Arctic Roadmap 2014-2018,” Navy Task<br />

Force Climate Change, February 2014: 7, accessed<br />

November 1, 2014.<br />

http://www.navy.mil/docs/USN_arctic_roadmap.pdf<br />

35 “U.S. Sanctions Cloud Oil Discovery in the Russian<br />

Arctic with Uncertainty,” Forbes, October 6, 2014,<br />

accessed on November 10, 2014.<br />

http://www.forbes.com/sites/greatspeculations/2014/<br />

10/06/u-s-sanctions-cloud-oil-discovery-in-the-russianarctic-with-uncertainty/.<br />

36 Ivshina. “Russian Oil Industry Facing a Deep<br />

Freeze.”<br />

37 Mansur Mirov, “Russia’s Failing Designs for Arctic<br />

oil Exploration,” Al Jazeera, March 19, <strong>2015</strong>, accessed<br />

on April 22, <strong>2015</strong>.<br />

http://www.aljazeera.com/indepth/features/<strong>2015</strong>/03/<br />

russia-failing-designs-arctic-oil-exploration-<br />

150316075032235.html<br />

38 Politics: Too Much to Fight Over,”<br />

39 Blank, ed. “Russia in the Arctic,” 19.<br />

126 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 126


military personnel and equipment capable of<br />

operating in polar conditions, and the lack of<br />

any immediate response capabilities in the<br />

event of hostilities. 40 More than 10,000 miles<br />

of Russia’s Arctic coastlines are not covered<br />

by radio, among other weaknesses, leading<br />

Russia to purchase information from the<br />

United States or Canada. 41 While Russia has<br />

the largest military presence in the Arctic,<br />

including the world’s largest fleet of<br />

icebreakers, this force is antiquated, making it<br />

technologically insufficient for current Arctic<br />

missions, and too geographically concentrated<br />

in the Kola Peninsula to be an offensive<br />

force. 42 U.S. ICBM submarines in the region<br />

are a far more potent force than Russia’s own<br />

subsurface fleet. 43 These weaknesses, in<br />

conjunction with weak conventional forces,<br />

are driving efforts to prioritize nuclear<br />

deterrence capabilities. 44 Russia will continue<br />

to build its nuclear deterrence capabilities as<br />

well for defensive purposes, but this will take<br />

several years due to the ongoing economic<br />

slowdown and backlog of work that needs to<br />

be done.<br />

Offensive Russian military action in<br />

the region is therefore unlikely. This would be<br />

detrimental to resource access and elicit an<br />

aggressive response from NATO. 45 Likewise,<br />

in the next three years the primary issue is not<br />

legal or military access to enough resources, it<br />

is financial ability and technological know-<br />

40 Yekaterina Kravtsova. “Russia Builds Up Arctic<br />

Forces as Resource Fight Intensifies,” Moscow Times,<br />

December 25, 2013, accessed on November 17, 2014.<br />

http://www.themoscowtimes.com/news/article/russia<br />

-builds-up-arctic-forces-as-resource-fightintensifies/492100.html<br />

41 Blank, ed. “Russia in the Arctic,” 84.<br />

42 Ibid., p 51 and 56<br />

43 Rebecca Bluitt. “Cold, Cold War: Putin Talks Tough<br />

Over US Rivalry,” ABC News, December 5, 2013,<br />

accessed on November 15, 2014.<br />

http://abcnews.go.com/Blotter/cold-cold-war-putintalks-tough-us-artic/story?id=21110178<br />

44 Blank, ed., “Russia in the Arctic,” 113.<br />

45 Sharp, “The Implications of Ice Melt on Arctic<br />

Security,” 304.<br />

how to make use of already undisputed<br />

resources with Russia’s recognized territorial<br />

claims. Rather, Russian capabilities appear<br />

better aligned with their stated goals to<br />

expand border patrols, 46 increase the size of<br />

the coast guard, and capacity-building<br />

measures in the form of providing security for<br />

Russian commercial and scientific<br />

expeditions. 47<br />

Since major Russian naval<br />

construction projects were halted in response<br />

to the 2008 financial crisis, current sanctions<br />

and the resulting economic decline are also<br />

limiting military production. 48 Russia’s finance<br />

minister recently explained that Russia cannot<br />

afford to meet the Kremlin’s desired goal of a<br />

30% upgrade of military equipment by <strong>2015</strong><br />

and 70% by 2020. 49 This plan was created in<br />

2011, before the current sanctions were<br />

implemented that limit access to needed<br />

technology and specifically target the arms<br />

industry. Unless the government drastically<br />

diverts resources from the domestic economy,<br />

these upgrades will be impossible to achieve.<br />

Even if the money is available, it will take a<br />

long time to replace imported military<br />

technologies with domestic output. 50 Russia is<br />

far from meeting its stated goals for an Arctic<br />

military buildup for 2010-<strong>2015</strong> and is a long<br />

way from developing the Arctic as its strategic<br />

resource base by 2020. 51<br />

46 Gareth Jennings, “Russia to Deploy Orlan-10<br />

TUAVs to the Arctic in May,” IHS Jane’s 360, April 23,<br />

<strong>2015</strong>, accessed on April 25, <strong>2015</strong>.<br />

http://www.janes.com/article/50928/russia-to-deployorlan-10-tuavs-to-the-arctic-in-may<br />

47 Blank, ed., “Russia in the Arctic,” 110.<br />

48 Ibid. p. 84.<br />

49 Lidia Kelly. “Finance Minister Warns Russia Can’t<br />

Afford Military Spending Plan,” Reuters, October 7,<br />

2014, accessed November 5, 2014.<br />

http://www.reuters.com/article/2014/10/07/usrussia-economy-spending-defenceidUSKCN0HW1H420141007<br />

50 Ibid.<br />

51 Foundations of The Russian Federation’s State Policy in the<br />

Arctic Until 2020 and Beyond, September 18, 2008,<br />

accessed December 1, 2014.<br />

127 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 127


It is worth noting that Russia’s<br />

bellicose rhetoric regarding Arctic dominance<br />

plays successfully to domestic audiences. 52<br />

Taking these claims at face value would<br />

embolden the most extreme supporters of the<br />

buildup, when indicators point towards Russia<br />

enhancing its self-defense and Arctic<br />

exploration interests instead. However, some<br />

indicators of Russian aggression would<br />

include Russia’s withdrawal from the Arctic<br />

Council, its rejection of UNCLOS rules, and<br />

staking a unilateral claim to the desired areas<br />

coupled with a rapid buildup of offensive<br />

capabilities in the region.<br />

Russia’s capabilities are also limited by<br />

regional environmental constraints. New<br />

opportunities due to ice melt will not be<br />

realistically viable for several decades. The<br />

region remains expensive to operate in,<br />

requiring special technology and equipment<br />

and high insurance rates, as well as high<br />

transportation costs after resource<br />

extraction. 53 The region is dangerous to<br />

operate in due to shallow waters, ice drift, and<br />

months without sun. 54 Finally, it is laborious<br />

since few countries have the right vessels to<br />

travel safely through the region. 55 An<br />

environmental disaster (or a military attack)<br />

due to Russian activity in the region would<br />

result in international involvement and more<br />

scrutiny and possibly increased regulations.<br />

All of this provides incentive for Russia to act<br />

cautiously in the region and not give other<br />

states a reason to intervene. 56<br />

http://icr.arcticportal.org/index.php?option=com_con<br />

tent&view=article&id=1791%3<br />

52 Hilde, “The ‘new’ Arctic—the Military Dimension,”<br />

146.<br />

53 Keil, “The Arctic: A New Region of Conflict?” 179.<br />

54 Sharp, “The Implications of Ice Melt on Arctic<br />

Security,” 300.<br />

55 Ibid.<br />

56 Blank, ed., “Russia in the Arctic,” 24.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

The assessment of Russian capabilities<br />

is limited by information gaps involving<br />

intentions and capabilities. President Putin’s<br />

increasingly erratic behavior makes it difficult<br />

to assess his true intentions and the decisionmaking<br />

processes of his administration. It is<br />

also difficult to assess the full effect on the<br />

Russian economy that sanctions will have,<br />

given that these are all conditional measures<br />

taken with respect to Ukraine and could be<br />

withdrawn in the event of a settlement.<br />

Additionally, it is unknown whether Russian<br />

intentions will be deterred or accelerated by<br />

worsening economic conditions, and how<br />

much the government is willing to invest in<br />

the military at the risk of increased domestic<br />

hardships.<br />

The norm of cooperation in the Arctic<br />

is expected to continue through the next three<br />

years. However, several alternatives might<br />

derail this. Russia’s last official Arctic strategy<br />

was released in 2008, so it is possible that<br />

Russia could release a new, more aggressive<br />

strategy for the region. Since Russia has not<br />

ruled out the use of force in territorial<br />

disputes over the Arctic and has used force<br />

elsewhere to achieve its goals, this too is an<br />

option. 57 Russian annexation of the areas it<br />

has petitioned for under UNCLOS is not<br />

impossible given Russia’s seizure of the<br />

Crimea in 2014. The continuing decline in oil<br />

and gas prices could also lessen immediate<br />

Russian interests in the region. Alternatively,<br />

the overall economic deterioration and<br />

international isolation of Russia could create<br />

domestic unrest that requires more of Putin’s<br />

resources and time from any ventures in the<br />

far north.<br />

Russia’s intentions in the Arctic are<br />

increasing, driven by its hydrocarbon<br />

dependence and desire to return to great<br />

power status. However, its capabilities in the<br />

57 Sharp, “The Implications of Ice Melt on Arctic<br />

Security,” 304.<br />

128 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 128


Artic will remain weak as its economic decline<br />

inhibits modernization of the armed forces.<br />

Given the combination of economic<br />

incentive, national security, identity issues, and<br />

domestic politics, the Arctic is likely to<br />

become a region of conflict in the future.<br />

Geographic, climatologic, and technological<br />

barriers will continue to impede Russian<br />

efforts, and those of other nations. The high<br />

political and financial cost that any conflict<br />

would impose on resource access makes acts<br />

of aggression in the next three years unlikely. 58<br />

ROMA PARHAD is<br />

completing her M.A. in<br />

International Relations<br />

this year. She is<br />

interested in<br />

international security<br />

issues, the Middle<br />

East, ethnic and<br />

religious pluralism,<br />

and conflict mediation.<br />

Her past experience in<br />

related fields includes work with the Council<br />

on Foreign Relations, U.S. Congress, conflict<br />

mediation programs, newspaper and radio<br />

news outlets, and think tanks. She is<br />

currently interning at the Carnegie Council’s<br />

journal Ethics and International Affairs and<br />

attempting to write a thesis on ethnic<br />

minorities and security in Iran.<br />

58 Blank, ed., “Russia in the Arctic,” 108-9.<br />

129 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 129


“Creating an academic<br />

program to answer the<br />

needs of society”<br />

A Conversation with Dr.<br />

Michael Williams<br />

Jordan Clifford<br />

D<br />

r. Michael Williams became<br />

director of the International<br />

Relations Program at NYU in<br />

the fall of 2014. Williams undertook his<br />

undergraduate work in the international<br />

relations program at the University of<br />

Delaware, receiving an honors BA with<br />

distinction. He then received an MA from<br />

Humboldt University in Germany, where<br />

he studied contemporary European<br />

history. He completed his doctorate at the<br />

London School of Economics under the<br />

direction of Christopher Coker where he<br />

wrote on the social construction of risk in<br />

the North Atlantic, looking in particular at<br />

how elites of the NATO alliance<br />

constructed and responded to security<br />

risks in the post-Cold War world. But<br />

what sparked his interest in international<br />

relations in the first place?<br />

MJW: I was always really interested in<br />

history and foreign affairs from a<br />

historical perspective, but I think it was<br />

when I was a senior in high school that I<br />

became interested. I was selected to go as<br />

part of a student delegation to Ukraine<br />

and Russia for a winter session. We went<br />

to Crimea for six weeks and we studied<br />

Russian language, culture, and politics. We<br />

stayed at this huge Soviet children’s camp<br />

called Artek. I also stayed with a Russian<br />

family living in Ukraine. I became very<br />

close friends with one of the girls and her<br />

family, and thought to myself, “their<br />

family is just like my family and they seem<br />

to want the same things.” I had studied<br />

the Cold War in high school, but I just<br />

didn’t understand why the U.S. and the<br />

Soviet Union had a war. So it got me<br />

interested in the causes of war and the<br />

conditions of peace, which is the root of<br />

the study of international relations.<br />

<strong>JPI</strong>: Why did you choose to do your MA in<br />

Germany and then your PhD in the UK?<br />

MJW: I did my masters in Germany<br />

because one of my German professors<br />

suggested I apply for a scholarship for a<br />

year in Germany when I was a sophomore<br />

in university. I said to my professor, “Frau<br />

Busch! My German isn’t good enough.”<br />

She told me that I wasn’t going to<br />

Germany because I spoke perfect<br />

Germen, but to perfect my German. So I<br />

applied, thinking I would never get it—<br />

but I got it.<br />

The next thing I knew was that I had a<br />

full scholarship and had to take a leave of<br />

absence for a year from Delaware. I went<br />

to Germany and matriculated at the<br />

University of Hamburg as a normal<br />

German student. I had no help, no<br />

support. I didn’t speak German that well<br />

by the way. I had taken it in high school<br />

and university, but I wouldn’t say I spoke<br />

German. You don’t really learn a language<br />

until you live the language. I got to<br />

Hamburg in August for a language class<br />

and German universities don’t start until<br />

October, so it was hard to meet people. It<br />

was tough, my mom would tell me that I<br />

could come home, but I’m not a quitter! I<br />

stayed and it was the best year of my life.<br />

Hamburg is still my favorite city in<br />

Germany.<br />

130 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 130


After living in Hamburg for a year, a great<br />

international port city, I was so depressed<br />

when I came back home to Delaware.<br />

Delaware is awesome, but after you’ve<br />

lived in a world city that’s been there for<br />

1,100 years, it hits you. I wanted to go<br />

back to Germany to study German and<br />

European relations.<br />

I applied to one university that accepted<br />

foreign degrees—the German university<br />

system at the time was very introverted—<br />

and I got a full float because they were<br />

eager to get good American students. My<br />

boss at the time—Senator Joe Biden—<br />

said, “Go to Europe, kid. Anyone can<br />

study Germany at Georgetown.” So I left<br />

and went to Europe. After that I applied<br />

to PhD programs, but the LSE was in<br />

London, and I loved LSE—it was one of<br />

the most interesting and intellectually<br />

stimulating places I’ve ever been and<br />

NYU reminds me of that. I loved it and<br />

wouldn’t change anything.<br />

<strong>JPI</strong>: You’ve had the opportunity to work in<br />

academia and government, what do you like about<br />

each?<br />

MJW: Academia is good because you have<br />

free range of inquiry and a lot of time to<br />

think, which is good and bad. I think part<br />

of the problem with scholarship is that it<br />

can be introverted and there’s a danger<br />

that it becomes focused on how to study<br />

international affairs rather than studying<br />

international affairs. Then your<br />

scholarship is very much limited in<br />

efficacy when it comes to policy and<br />

thinking about the real world as opposed<br />

to a theoretical world. Theory is there to<br />

help us explain the world, but it is also<br />

based on ideal concepts that usually aren’t<br />

present.<br />

There is a danger that scholars are<br />

divorced from reality. The best<br />

scholarship, in my opinion, speaks to<br />

reality, but also is uncompromising in its<br />

rigor and it’s thinking. This is the<br />

downside to the policy world, where the<br />

scholarship is not necessarily as rigorous.<br />

In the think tank world, it can be very<br />

transitory and superficial, but at the same<br />

time you’re working closely with policy<br />

makers. Policy makers are highly<br />

intelligent and motivated, but are under<br />

intense pressure. You don’t have time to<br />

think about the history of the Middle East<br />

and how it relates to what is happening<br />

when you have 24 hours to turn out a<br />

memo for the President on issue X. In my<br />

experience, working with policy makers in<br />

the U.S. has a nice advantage in the sense<br />

that scholars have the ability to go into<br />

government. We have a revolving door at<br />

the highest levels of bureaucracy that<br />

means that you can think about the world<br />

while you’re on the outside and you can<br />

then bring some of that knowledge to<br />

contemporary policy challenges.<br />

The downside is then maybe you’re too<br />

idealistic and think you can change the<br />

world; or you know a ton of information<br />

but don’t know how to work the<br />

bureaucracy. In Europe, being in civil<br />

service means that you know how to ‘get<br />

things done’. And that’s the hallmark of<br />

someone who wants to bridge that gap,<br />

someone who is knowledgeable and<br />

rigorous in their study of the world, but<br />

who also understands how to disseminate<br />

that information in a way that’s accessible<br />

to people who have little time to make<br />

decisions. Also, working the machinery if<br />

you’re in administration—if you’re the<br />

Senior Director for NATO-Europe, you<br />

need to know Europe, but you also have<br />

to know how to make the trains run on<br />

time. If you’re a Dean you are ideally an<br />

131 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 131


accomplished scholar, but you can also<br />

make things happen administratively.<br />

<strong>JPI</strong>: Where have you worked in government and<br />

what was the most interesting?<br />

MJW: Much of my government work has<br />

been as a consultant. I’ve worked for<br />

NATO headquarters, for NATO Allied<br />

Command Transformation in Virginia.<br />

I’ve done consultancy projects for the<br />

State Department, for the DOD, the<br />

Canadian Department of Foreign Affairs<br />

and International Trade (DFAIT), and the<br />

Department of National Defense in<br />

Canada. As a young man I was lucky<br />

enough to work for the chairman of<br />

Senate Foreign Relations Committee, Joe<br />

Biden. I’ve spent time at the State<br />

Department in London in addition to<br />

consulting on post-conflict<br />

reconstruction; and then I worked for a<br />

year as a special advisor for a deputy<br />

German Defense Minister. I’d say the two<br />

coolest experiences would be my time at<br />

the German Ministry of Defense and at<br />

the State Department in London. The<br />

embassy in London was great. The foreign<br />

service officers were some of the most<br />

interesting, intelligent, hard-working,<br />

overworked people I’ve met—I’m still<br />

good friends with some of them. And<br />

they were brilliant, and very influential<br />

role models for me. In Germany, it was<br />

great because I was an insider, but also an<br />

outsider. So sitting one rung down from<br />

the cabinet minister really gave me an<br />

interesting insight and a chance to be a<br />

different voice. So I’d say it’s a tie<br />

between the two. I’ve been very fortunate<br />

for someone relatively early on in his<br />

career and who has been relatively<br />

academic to actually have the time to do<br />

that.<br />

<strong>JPI</strong>: So how was the transition from student life<br />

to government and from student life to academia?<br />

MJW: It wasn’t always without error. The<br />

hardest transition from academia is that<br />

the scholarly community writes differently<br />

than the professionals do. So the first two<br />

months at the Embassy, I had everything I<br />

wrote come back with red ink everywhere<br />

because I was writing like an academic,<br />

which is how I was trained. Learning to<br />

write diplomatic cables and briefs was a<br />

challenge—a good challenge, but a<br />

challenge.<br />

When you think you’re very good with<br />

your writing and the diplomat is marking<br />

everything in red ink, it’s a humbling<br />

experience, but it’s important to know<br />

what you don’t know. My parents taught<br />

me that so I realized that I don’t know<br />

how to do everything well, but I can learn<br />

something new; and I did, it was<br />

informative. I was able to do things some<br />

of my other colleagues were unable to do<br />

because they didn’t have that early<br />

experience that enabled you to become<br />

more solidified in your ways and navigate<br />

between the two. And then I had to do it<br />

in German in Berlin!<br />

The downside is that policy work can<br />

bastardize you in the academic<br />

community—it can be difficult to bridge<br />

the two, but I think my publications and<br />

my work with Cambridge help to show<br />

that I have bona fides as a scholar in<br />

addition to understanding how policy<br />

works. And as Bismarck said: “It is like<br />

sausage-making.”<br />

<strong>JPI</strong>: Then you transitioned to NYU. Why?<br />

MJW: The appeal of NYU was its stellar<br />

academic reputation; and I’m building the<br />

program and I like that. I love teaching<br />

132 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 132


and I enjoy researching, but I like the<br />

situation, the challenge, and being busy. I<br />

do love teaching, and if there is any legacy<br />

I could leave it will be with the students<br />

that I teach. The most rewarding thing is<br />

when you get an email from someone<br />

after class saying how much he or she<br />

enjoyed it, or if they write to you years<br />

down the line saying how influential you<br />

were—that makes me feel wonderful. I<br />

like the idea of creating an academic<br />

program that answers the needs we have<br />

as a society. This along with preparing<br />

people who are going to work in that<br />

world—in NGOs, international<br />

organizations, scholarship—and helping<br />

with their goals was the real draw. I also<br />

wanted to be closer to my family after 13<br />

years away. Mom and Dad are pretty<br />

happy to have me within 100 miles of<br />

‘home’.<br />

<strong>JPI</strong>: So what have been your initiatives thus far to<br />

expand the program?<br />

MJW: I have been super busy and NYU is<br />

lucky to have me (laughs).<br />

On a more serious note, the previous<br />

director laid an amazing foundation for<br />

the program. It was up to me to do some<br />

of the framing and put the roof on. My<br />

goal has been to harness our increasingly<br />

limited academic resources more<br />

efficiently—it must be that German<br />

influence on my thinking. So the approach<br />

has been how a program can grow under<br />

such conditions—can we make it more<br />

than some of its parts? NYU has a lot of<br />

international relations parts that have not<br />

been assembled in the most ingenious<br />

way. I have found my colleagues<br />

sympathetic to this thinking and very, very<br />

helpful.<br />

I have done a lot of diplomacy really, with<br />

what I have found to be very willing<br />

partners—in Russian and Slavic studies,<br />

European Mediterranean studies, Middle<br />

Eastern studies, the History department,<br />

and the Politics department—to build a<br />

program that is the ‘window on the world’<br />

as I call it at NYU. So getting professors<br />

to teach our courses, getting our students<br />

into those courses, and creating areas of<br />

specializations, e.g. IR with European<br />

studies. I’m really proud that NYU Law<br />

agreed to launch IR with International<br />

Law. NYU Law is one of the top five law<br />

schools in America and probably the best<br />

for international law in the country. I<br />

think that speaks a lot to the quality of our<br />

students, and also to the capacity of NYU<br />

to work well together.<br />

I have had excellent administrators to<br />

work with, from our own Tina Lam, who<br />

is a superstar, on to the Dean of the<br />

Graduate School, Laurie Benton; the<br />

Dean of the Masters College, David<br />

Giovanella; the Senior Vice Provost, Matt<br />

Santirocco; Barbara Weinstein in history;<br />

and David Stasavage in Politics.<br />

<strong>JPI</strong>: So where do you see the program going from<br />

here?<br />

MJW: I want to see the program ranked as<br />

one of the top ten in Foreign Policy<br />

magazine’s top masters programs for<br />

international relations in the world within<br />

a decade—right now NYU is 24th in the<br />

world, which is very good, but it’s not<br />

representative of what NYU offers—<br />

partly because NYU is a big organization<br />

with lots of room for entrepreneurship.<br />

Things grow and develop, but they don’t<br />

always grow and develop together. One of<br />

the reasons why they hired me is that I’m<br />

a very outgoing person, and I believe<br />

NYU can easily rank ten within the<br />

133 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 133


decade if we make more effective use of<br />

resources. I also want to develop area<br />

specialties, probably in law and global<br />

governance around the UN, as well as<br />

international business, and private and<br />

public political risk.<br />

<strong>JPI</strong>: What does your work focus on currently? Do<br />

you have any projects you’re working on?<br />

MJW: Administration at NYU (laughs). I<br />

just finished a project looking at how the<br />

U.S. uses law and technology to wage wars<br />

with a liberal framework. One of my next<br />

projects is the evolution of weapons and<br />

law in humane warfare. I’m also working<br />

on a project on successful negotiations in<br />

international relations, what Henry<br />

Kissinger called the ‘balance of<br />

dissatisfaction’. I’m in a bit of a lull and<br />

focused on NYU, but currently I’m<br />

talking to publishers and working on a<br />

textbook for Cambridge.<br />

<strong>JPI</strong>: What are some of the trends going on in the<br />

world of IR today?<br />

MJW: Well, it depends on where you’re<br />

seated, right? It seems to me that the U.S.<br />

has overwhelmingly veered towards a very<br />

quantitative, rational choice<br />

methodologies geared around structural<br />

realism and neo-realism. I think<br />

quantification stems from economics and<br />

increasingly economics is moving away<br />

from rational actor-choice paradigms and<br />

some of that dry political science. And it<br />

seems to me that there is a little bit more<br />

of an interest in neo-classical realism. I<br />

don’t think that post-modernism or poststructuralism<br />

is going to be a benchmark<br />

in American IR as it is in Europe, but I do<br />

think that meta-theory constructivism will<br />

continue to make inroads.<br />

Neo-classical realism may evolve to have<br />

more space for agency as opposed to<br />

structure, but that in itself is fighting with<br />

the quantitative methodology approach. I<br />

think there is a danger in the American<br />

academy of becoming reductionist and<br />

quantitative and missing out in granularity.<br />

So I hope that adjusts itself a bit, I am a<br />

British trained doctorate so I am<br />

prejudiced in that regard, but I do think<br />

there is a lot more policy input from<br />

historians and scholars who are trained in<br />

interdisciplinary approaches to area<br />

studies than those who are highly<br />

quantitative.<br />

I don’t think that its rocket science to say<br />

that there is a shifting balance of power.<br />

Relative to other powers, America is in<br />

decline. The U.S. will remain the foremost<br />

economic and military power for quite<br />

some time, but as John Mearsheimer says,<br />

it’s a superpower, but not a global<br />

hegemon. It’s a regional hegemon. The<br />

U.S. strategy is contingent on maintaining<br />

imbalance in other regions so that no<br />

other regional hegemon can emerge—<br />

that’s going to be very difficult to do in<br />

Asia where China has the aspirations and<br />

capabilities to do so. I also think that<br />

rising levels of nationalism could be an<br />

issue. We’ve seen it domestically, but we<br />

also see it in Europe —a pull away from<br />

integration and transnational politics. Any<br />

student of history can recall the 1930s and<br />

think that nationalism is not a great idea,<br />

but I’d keep an eye on people like Marine<br />

Le Pen in France—I hope it’s superficial,<br />

but well see.<br />

So there’s a shifting balance of power,<br />

America has to accommodate a more<br />

diverse world—a collective world of<br />

power; not just with China but also with a<br />

resurgent Russia, that is basically an Upper<br />

Volta with nuclear weapons; with a<br />

134 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 134


shifting regional balances in Europe and<br />

Germany; and with Latin America, where<br />

the U.S. has always had a sketchy<br />

reputation. This is probably one of the<br />

most interesting and scary periods of time<br />

to live in since the end of the Cold War, if<br />

not even further back. So it’s a great time<br />

to study IR!<br />

JORDAN CLIFFORD is an MA candidate<br />

in International Relations at New York<br />

University. He graduated with honors and<br />

distinction from Binghamton University<br />

with a BA in political science, having<br />

written his thesis on the mechanisms of<br />

successful revolutions and the role of the<br />

military. He serves as editorial manager<br />

for International Politics Reviews, a<br />

research assistant at the Center for<br />

Behavioral Research in Business at NYU<br />

Stern, and as an international board<br />

member for Dorm Room Diplomacy. His<br />

work has been published by World Policy<br />

Journal and International Relations and<br />

Security Network.<br />

135 <strong>Spring</strong> <strong>2015</strong> 135

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!