10.07.2015 Views

Global Ageing: What is at stake? - by Börsch-Supan - Oxford Institute ...

Global Ageing: What is at stake? - by Börsch-Supan - Oxford Institute ...

Global Ageing: What is at stake? - by Börsch-Supan - Oxford Institute ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Copyright 2006 <strong>by</strong> the<strong>Oxford</strong> <strong>Institute</strong> of <strong>Ageing</strong>AGEING HORIZONSIssue No. 4, 3–5<strong>Global</strong> <strong>Ageing</strong>: <strong>Wh<strong>at</strong></strong> <strong>is</strong> <strong>at</strong> Stake?Axel <strong>Börsch</strong>-<strong>Supan</strong>, University of Mannheim, GermanyAbstractA central question for econom<strong>is</strong>ts and politicians alike <strong>is</strong>how demographic change will affect the wealth of n<strong>at</strong>ions.Which countries will gain, which countries will lose in theintern<strong>at</strong>ional pecking order? Equally important <strong>is</strong> thequestion how these gains and losses can be influenced <strong>by</strong>public policy. With these two core questions in mind, th<strong>is</strong>brief paper reviews the most important economic challengesand opportunities due to global ageing for Europe.IntroductionThe expected change in the age structure in virtually allindustrialized countries – but also in many developingcountries – <strong>is</strong> dram<strong>at</strong>ic and will lead to a substantiallyhigher proportion of older people in the world. The ageingprocess deeply affects future labour, financial andcommodity markets. On a macroeconomic level, labour <strong>is</strong>becoming rel<strong>at</strong>ively scarce in the ageing countries whilecapital becomes rel<strong>at</strong>ively more abundant. Th<strong>is</strong> precipit<strong>at</strong>eschanges in the rel<strong>at</strong>ive price of labour, will lead to highercapital intensity, and might gener<strong>at</strong>e large intern<strong>at</strong>ionalflows of labour, capital and goods from the faster to theslower ageing countries. On a microeconomic level, theage composition of the labour force will change, whichmight affect labour productivity. Consumption and savingsp<strong>at</strong>terns are likely to alter when the elderly become a largerproportion of consumers and savers, with widespreadimplic<strong>at</strong>ions for capital and goods markets.While ageing <strong>is</strong> global, there are marked intern<strong>at</strong>ionaldifferences in the speed and the extent of the ageingprocesses. Even within the industrialized countries, differencesare large. Europe and Japan have already a mucholder popul<strong>at</strong>ion than North-America. Italy and Germanyare ageing faster than France and Gre<strong>at</strong> Britain. In Asia,some countries start from a rel<strong>at</strong>ively young popul<strong>at</strong>ion,but ageing <strong>is</strong> very quick. A particular dram<strong>at</strong>ic example <strong>is</strong>China. Due to the global<strong>is</strong><strong>at</strong>ion of our economies, no studyof ageing can d<strong>is</strong>regard these differential changes.Intern<strong>at</strong>ional flows of capital, goods and services, andlabour – in descending order of mobility – will be importantmechan<strong>is</strong>ms moder<strong>at</strong>ing the effects of popul<strong>at</strong>ionageing in each individual country.Labour marketsUnderstanding the development of the labour force duringthe next decades <strong>is</strong> crucial for any analys<strong>is</strong> of global ageingbecause the long run macroeconomic development <strong>is</strong> domin<strong>at</strong>ed<strong>by</strong> fundamentals such as the rel<strong>at</strong>ive scarcity oflabour and the rel<strong>at</strong>ive abundance of capital. The essentialmacroeconomic effects of popul<strong>at</strong>ion ageing are a changingbalance between capital and labour, and between laboursupply and demand for consumption. An ageing society hasrel<strong>at</strong>ively few workers for the ex<strong>is</strong>ting capital stock th<strong>at</strong>produces consumption goods for a still rel<strong>at</strong>ively largenumber of consumers. The fundamental parameter foreconomic performance during the ageing process <strong>is</strong> thereforethe r<strong>at</strong>io between workers and consumers.It <strong>is</strong> very unlikely th<strong>at</strong> the decline in th<strong>is</strong> r<strong>at</strong>io can becompens<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>by</strong> an equiproportional increase in productivityand/or capital accumul<strong>at</strong>ion. GDP in most Europeancountries will therefore almost surely decline, and thesecountries are likely to become members with a decliningweight among the G8/G20 countries.From a domestic consumer’s point of view, total GDPmight be less relevant than GDP per capita. However, totalpopul<strong>at</strong>ion sizes will stay rel<strong>at</strong>ively constant for mostEuropean countries until about 2035, maybe slightly decliningor increasing. Once the ba<strong>by</strong> boom gener<strong>at</strong>iondeceases, however, many European countries will face asignificantly declining popul<strong>at</strong>ion. Labour force as a shareof the adult popul<strong>at</strong>ion – the so called support r<strong>at</strong>io – willtherefore decline slower than total labour force. Forexample, the German support r<strong>at</strong>io <strong>is</strong> projected to declinefrom 56% in the year 2000 to 49% in the year 2035, a15%-decline in 25 years.Th<strong>is</strong> figure <strong>is</strong> useful because it demonstr<strong>at</strong>es the force ofageing in an understandable metric. A decline of 15% inthe 25 year period between 2010 and 2035 transl<strong>at</strong>es in aneg<strong>at</strong>ive growth r<strong>at</strong>e of around 0.45 percentage points perannum from 2010 to 2035. The long-term real productivitygrowth of a typical European economy <strong>is</strong> about 1.5%per annum. In other words, the neg<strong>at</strong>ive economic force ofageing, simply <strong>by</strong> reducing the number of workers availableto produce goods and services, corresponds to betweena quarter and a third of the average annual productivitygrowth. To compens<strong>at</strong>e for the lack of workers <strong>by</strong> higherproductivity of the ex<strong>is</strong>ting workers, total factor produc-AGEING HORIZONS Issue No 4OXFORD INSTITUTE OF AGEING3


tivity would need increase <strong>by</strong> 40%, probably an unreal<strong>is</strong>ticfigure.The variability range for th<strong>is</strong> forecast <strong>is</strong> large and almostentirely depends on future labour force particip<strong>at</strong>ion of theyoung, the elderly and the female. In most pessim<strong>is</strong>ticscenarios of unchanging labour force particip<strong>at</strong>ion, theimpact of the declining support r<strong>at</strong>io <strong>is</strong> huge. On the otherhand, in an optim<strong>is</strong>tic scenario of Denmark-style labourmarket reforms, the shift in the age structure <strong>is</strong> compens<strong>at</strong>edfor almost entirely <strong>by</strong> the increase in particip<strong>at</strong>ionr<strong>at</strong>es.Th<strong>is</strong> example bears several lessons for policy in times ofglobal ageing. First, the huge variability of the projectionsand the leverage of employment on GDP make clear th<strong>at</strong>it <strong>is</strong> important to better understand how public policy caninfluence labour force particip<strong>at</strong>ion r<strong>at</strong>es. Structuralreforms such as educ<strong>at</strong>ion reform and pension reform havepotentially huge “side-effects” on GDP growth throughtheir impact on employment, over and above the oftenmore prominently d<strong>is</strong>cussed impacts on social budgets.Second, the above example shows how strongly the differentialforce of global ageing depends on to the extent towhich an increasing quality of labour will compens<strong>at</strong>e forthe decreasing quantity of labour. “Side effects” of structuralreforms on productivity may in the long-run domin<strong>at</strong>eany direct but st<strong>at</strong>ic effects, because they change thegrowth p<strong>at</strong>h of the economy.Not only the size but also the age structure of the workingpopul<strong>at</strong>ion will change radically in the coming decades.We again use Germany as an example for how dram<strong>at</strong>icthe change will be. The modal age of the German workforce in the year 2000 was around age 36; in 2010, th<strong>is</strong>peak age will increase to 46 years; and a further 10 yearsl<strong>at</strong>er it will be 54 years. The ba<strong>by</strong> boomers then retire –the age d<strong>is</strong>tribution curve fl<strong>at</strong>tens out and changes verylittle in the following decades.Th<strong>is</strong> fundamental change in the age structure of theworking popul<strong>at</strong>ion will have profound effects on themicroeconomics and the sociology of the labour market.The most important – and most controversial – aspect <strong>is</strong>the potential effect on labour productivity. If labourproductivity <strong>is</strong> age dependent, a shift in the age structurewill also bring about a change in aggreg<strong>at</strong>e productivity,even if age-specific productivity were to remain constant.We know little about the size of these effects. R<strong>at</strong>her, moreresearch on age-specific productivity <strong>is</strong> needed to betterunderstand whether ageing economies will suffer from aproductivity decline, amplifying the effects of a shrinkingquantity of labour. At the very least, however, we understandth<strong>at</strong> further educ<strong>at</strong>ion increases productivity – andherein lies an important policy message: prevent all actionsth<strong>at</strong> make further educ<strong>at</strong>ion less <strong>at</strong>tractive, and strengthenall steps th<strong>at</strong> increase the investment value of further educ<strong>at</strong>ion– such as a l<strong>at</strong>er retirement age.Interactions between labour, product andcapital marketsThe labour market <strong>is</strong> not insul<strong>at</strong>ed from other markets. It<strong>is</strong> not only directly affected <strong>by</strong> popul<strong>at</strong>ion ageing, but alsoindirectly <strong>by</strong> ageing-induced changes in product and capitalmarkets.Product demand will change, since an older popul<strong>at</strong>ion ofconsumers has different preferences and needs than ayounger popul<strong>at</strong>ion. Consumption demand may also declinefor <strong>at</strong> least two reasons. First, because GDP per capita willdecline in the face of a shrinking labour force unless th<strong>is</strong><strong>is</strong> offset <strong>by</strong> higher capital input and productivity. Secondand more subtly, it <strong>is</strong> likely th<strong>at</strong> more retirement incomecomes from asset income which fluctu<strong>at</strong>es more than annuitizedpension and labour income. Th<strong>is</strong> will increaseprecautionary savings and depress consumption, given afixed level of income.Consumption behavior changes with increasing age. Forexample, spending on goods in the group “transport andcommunic<strong>at</strong>ion” falls over the life cycle, while goods inthe “health and hygiene” group, as well as costs of shelter,account for a growing share of older households’ budgets.Hence, if the age d<strong>is</strong>tribution of an economy <strong>is</strong> changing,the composition of consumption will change accordingly.Most notably the aggreg<strong>at</strong>ed expenditure on health willincrease during the ageing process while the correspondingspending on transport will decline.Changing product demand will then precipit<strong>at</strong>e shifts insectoral labour demand. Employment in the health sectorwill increase; it will decline in the transport sector. Someestim<strong>at</strong>es suggest th<strong>at</strong> more than a sixth of all workers willneed to change their jobs due to popul<strong>at</strong>ion ageing.Labour supply <strong>is</strong> also affected <strong>by</strong> capital market fluctu<strong>at</strong>ions.The more retirement income <strong>is</strong> provided throughfunded pension income (e.g., 401k plans or other individualaccounts invested in the stock market), stock marketperformance will, <strong>at</strong> the margin, affect the retirement dec<strong>is</strong>ionof workers as well as their consumption demand.Understanding th<strong>is</strong> mechan<strong>is</strong>m <strong>is</strong> important for analyses ofglobal ageing since it may substantially amplify capitalmarket d<strong>is</strong>turbances. Stock markets have exhibited hugeswings, and we do not fully understand how bubblesemerge and even less how to predict and prevent them.Th<strong>is</strong> topic has a clear political dimension since the flexibilityof choosing the retirement age <strong>is</strong> a core transm<strong>is</strong>sionmechan<strong>is</strong>m for these interactions between the capitalmarket on one side and labour and product markets on theother side.Capital marketsCapital markets play a crucial role in global ageing sincecapital <strong>is</strong> the factor which moves with the least frictionsAGEING HORIZONS Issue No 4OXFORD INSTITUTE OF AGEING4

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!