10.07.2015 Views

Competition Law in Vietnam: A Toolkit - Consumer Unity & Trust ...

Competition Law in Vietnam: A Toolkit - Consumer Unity & Trust ...

Competition Law in Vietnam: A Toolkit - Consumer Unity & Trust ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


CONTENTSForeword ....................................................................................... iPreface ......................................................................................... iiiAcronyms .................................................................................... vii1. Introduction .............................................................................. 1An Overview of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> ...................... 22. About the Market Economy .................................................... 52.1 Market and Prices – How they Work? ........................................... 52.2 Governments and the Rule of <strong>Law</strong> vs Free Markets ...................... 63. Market and <strong>Competition</strong> ......................................................... 83.1 <strong>Competition</strong> .................................................................................... 83.2 Relevant Market ............................................................................. 93.3 Market Share & Structure ............................................................ 113.4 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> & Policy .......................................................... 134. Restrictive Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Practices ................................................ 154.1 Market Power ............................................................................... 154.2 Per se or Rule of Reason? ............................................................ 174.3 Anticompetitive Agreements ........................................................ 184.4 Horizontal Agreements among Competitors ................................ 194.5 Vertical Agreements <strong>in</strong> the Distribution/Sale of Products............ 284.6 Abuse of Dom<strong>in</strong>ant Position ........................................................ 365. Enforcement of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> Aga<strong>in</strong>st RBPs ......... 455.1 Detection of Violations ................................................................ 455.2 Obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Proof of Violations ...................................................... 485.3 Preserv<strong>in</strong>g Proof of Violations ..................................................... 516. Mergers & Acquisitions ..........................................................536.1 Dist<strong>in</strong>ction between M&As .......................................................... 536.2 Varieties of M&As ....................................................................... 546.3 Concerns about M&As................................................................. 546.4 Merger Review ............................................................................. 556.5 Information <strong>in</strong> Merger Review ..................................................... 566.6 Merger Remedies ......................................................................... 586.7 Jo<strong>in</strong>t Ventures ............................................................................... 61


7. Unfair Trade Practices: <strong>Competition</strong> &<strong>Consumer</strong> Protection ............................................................. 637.1 Unfair Trade Practices ................................................................ 647.2 Mislead<strong>in</strong>g Advertis<strong>in</strong>g ............................................................... 667.3 Pyramid Schemes ........................................................................ 678. Cross-Border Issues ................................................................708.1 Market Power <strong>in</strong> Global or Export Markets................................ 708.2 Barriers to Import <strong>Competition</strong> ................................................... 728.3 Foreign Investment-related <strong>Competition</strong> Issues .......................... 728.4 IPRs-related <strong>Competition</strong> Issues ................................................. 738.5 Deal<strong>in</strong>g with Cross-border Issues under the <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> ......................................................................... 749. <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> vs Intellectual Property <strong>Law</strong>s .................779.1 IPRs Standards as <strong>Competition</strong> Regulation ................................ 789.2 Regulation of the Exercise of IPRs though <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> .... 789.3 <strong>Competition</strong> Concerns <strong>in</strong> Licens<strong>in</strong>g Agreements ........................ 799.4 IPRs and the Abuse of a Dom<strong>in</strong>ant Position ............................... 819.5 Refusal to Deal ............................................................................ 829.6 Compulsory Licens<strong>in</strong>g ................................................................ 829.7 Parallel Import ............................................................................ 8310. Essential Elements for Success...............................................8610.1 Sequenc<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> Implementation .................... 8610.2 Build<strong>in</strong>g a Healthy <strong>Competition</strong> Culture ................................... 8711. The Desired Framework for <strong>Vietnam</strong> ...................................9511.1 Appropriate Revision of Certa<strong>in</strong> Provisions of the <strong>Law</strong> ........... 9511.2 Clear Differentiation between Horizontal and Vertical<strong>Competition</strong> Restra<strong>in</strong>ts .............................................................. 9611.3 Publication of Reader-friendly Implementation Guidel<strong>in</strong>es ...... 9611.4 More Comprehensive Coverage of the <strong>Law</strong> .............................. 9611.5 Specific Regulation over IPRs-related <strong>Competition</strong> Issues ....... 9711.6 Extension of Jurisdiction beyond Territorial Boundaries .......... 9711.7 Build<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Competition</strong> Authorities’ Human Resources ........ 9711.8 Independence/Autonomy of the <strong>Competition</strong> Authority ........... 9711.9 Active Involvement of <strong>Consumer</strong> and other CSOs.................... 98


LIST OF BOXESBox 1: Cartel of Cement Manufacturers and the Action by the MCA ......... 21Box 2: Syndicate System <strong>in</strong> Surface Transportation .................................... 23Box 3: Bloc Calendar – Cartel or an Efficiency-Enhanc<strong>in</strong>g Agreement ...... 24Box 4: A Case of Bid Rigg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> ................................................... 25Box 5: Complementary Bidd<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Pr<strong>in</strong>ters ................................................. 26Box 6: India’s Pharma Retail Cartel............................................................. 27Box 7:South Africa Tribunal Puts Brakes on M<strong>in</strong>imum Resale PriceMa<strong>in</strong>tenance ..................................................................................... 30Box 8: Hungarian Book Publishers <strong>in</strong> Trouble ............................................ 32Box 9: Ceylon Oxygen Escapes Exclusive Deal<strong>in</strong>g Charge ........................ 33Box 10: Promotional Strategy Foreclosed New Entrant <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>Beer Market ...................................................................................... 34Box 11: Ghana: Manufacturer vs Manufacturer............................................. 35Box 12: Tie-up Sales of Gas Stoves with Supply of Gas Connection ............ 37Box 13: Tied Sale Practices <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> Markets ........................................... 38Box 14: Local Bus<strong>in</strong>essman Squares up to Sasol .......................................... 38Box 15: Promotion or Predatory Pric<strong>in</strong>g: Does Viettel Violate the<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>? ............................................................................ 39Box 16: Predatory Practices <strong>in</strong> the Beer Sector <strong>in</strong> Zimbabwe ....................... 40Box 17: Viettel Mobile Faces Bankruptcy due to VNPT’s Monopoly .......... 41Box 18: IPRs over Weekly TV Guide Abused............................................... 42Box 19: Merger Led to Monopoly <strong>in</strong> the Cable TV Sector ........................... 57Box 20: South African Pharma Mergers: Conditions for Aspen .................... 59Box 21: The Rothmans of Pall Mall/ British American TobaccoMerger <strong>in</strong> Zimbabwe ........................................................................ 60Box 22: Jo<strong>in</strong>t Distribution of Polyethylene Covers........................................ 62Box 23: Mislead<strong>in</strong>g Advertis<strong>in</strong>g & Bait-and-Switch ..................................... 65Box 24: Giant Supermarkets Misled <strong>Consumer</strong>s <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a ...................... 66Box 25: Multi-level Market<strong>in</strong>g Firm Faces Fraud Probe ............................... 68Box 26: The Graphite Electrodes Cartel and its Effects on Develop<strong>in</strong>gCountry Steel Producers ................................................................... 71Box 27: International Patent <strong>Law</strong>s Hurt Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries ..................... 75Box 28: Microsoft’s Abuse of Dom<strong>in</strong>ance ..................................................... 80Box 29: Chile Allows Parallel Import to Promote <strong>Competition</strong> .................... 83Box 30: M<strong>in</strong>istry of Health to Regulate Foreign Drugs, Medic<strong>in</strong>e Prices ..... 84Box 31: Importation and Retail<strong>in</strong>g of Compact Discs ................................... 85


FOREWORD<strong>Competition</strong> has been a backbone area <strong>in</strong> the work of the <strong>Vietnam</strong> <strong>Competition</strong>Adm<strong>in</strong>istration Department (VCAD), especially s<strong>in</strong>ce the adoption of the<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> by the National Assembly of <strong>Vietnam</strong> on December 03,2004. With the major functions of assist<strong>in</strong>g the M<strong>in</strong>ister of Trade <strong>in</strong> stateadm<strong>in</strong>istration over competition and consumer protection issues, as well astrade remedies concern<strong>in</strong>g imported goods, the VCAD has been mak<strong>in</strong>g itsbest efforts towards:• Promot<strong>in</strong>g a fair competition environment <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>;• Protect<strong>in</strong>g enterprises and consumer’s <strong>in</strong>terests aga<strong>in</strong>st competitionrestrictive activities;• Prevent<strong>in</strong>g unfair competition practices;• Handl<strong>in</strong>g consumer protection;• Establish<strong>in</strong>g a more competitive and supportive environment for domestic<strong>in</strong>dustries; and• Support<strong>in</strong>g domestic <strong>in</strong>dustries to prevent and deal with foreign antidump<strong>in</strong>g,anti-subsidy and safeguard cases.<strong>Vietnam</strong> has embarked on a comprehensive market-oriented economic reformprogramme, generally referred to as Doi Moi, s<strong>in</strong>ce 1986, with significantachievements <strong>in</strong> terms of socio-economic as well as political and culturaldevelopment. Prior to that, <strong>Vietnam</strong> followed the model of a centrally plannedeconomy, <strong>in</strong> which markets were underdeveloped and the concept of‘competition’ was not much alienated. S<strong>in</strong>ce the open<strong>in</strong>g up of the economy,together with ga<strong>in</strong>s as mentioned above, anticompetitive and unfair competitionpractices among enterprises have also become rampant, threaten<strong>in</strong>g thelegitimate rights and <strong>in</strong>terests of bus<strong>in</strong>ess and consumers alike, and hamper<strong>in</strong>gthe bus<strong>in</strong>ess environment. In that context, VCAD has been play<strong>in</strong>g an importantrole <strong>in</strong> build<strong>in</strong>g a healthy competition culture and promot<strong>in</strong>g national economicgrowth.<strong>Competition</strong> policy and law is a new field to <strong>Vietnam</strong>. Therefore, cooperationwith and ga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g knowledge from <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>stitutions, as well as civilsociety organisations (CSOs) hav<strong>in</strong>g expertise on the same, are amongst theforemost priorities of VCAD. We have been cooperat<strong>in</strong>g closely with the civilsociety to <strong>in</strong>crease public awareness on the benefits of competition policy andlaw for consumers and for economic development <strong>in</strong> general.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>i


In this regard, CUTS and VCAD have undertaken close collaboration oncapacity build<strong>in</strong>g for VCAD staff as well as <strong>in</strong> various advocacy activities. Itis, thus, a pleasure for me to commend this research paper, ‘<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong><strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>’ published by CUTS. I personally f<strong>in</strong>d that the content isvery profound and useful for study<strong>in</strong>g of the subject <strong>in</strong> particular <strong>Vietnam</strong>context, and <strong>in</strong> general. I expect that this publication will be an active <strong>in</strong>gredient<strong>in</strong> the progresses towards establish<strong>in</strong>g a healthy competition scenario <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>and other countries as well.Dr D<strong>in</strong>h Thi My LoanFormer Director General<strong>Competition</strong> Adm<strong>in</strong>istration DepartmentM<strong>in</strong>istry of Trade of <strong>Vietnam</strong>ii<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Implement<strong>in</strong>g a competition law for the first time <strong>in</strong> any country, like <strong>Vietnam</strong>,is quite a difficult task. Firstly, there is a lack of understand<strong>in</strong>g of the relevantissues, which this toolkit tries to address. Secondly, the political economy ofthe country. Quite often a competition law creates new strictures which canaffect vested <strong>in</strong>terests, and thus there is a resistance to the implementation ofthe law. Thirdly, the implementation is often poor due to:• lack of political will;• lack of human and f<strong>in</strong>ancial resources;• opposition from vested <strong>in</strong>terests; and• lack of a strong civil society movement which can be a good ally and acountervail<strong>in</strong>g power to bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong>terests.The last factor is rather unfortunate, because an effective competition lawbr<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess welfare by curtail<strong>in</strong>g anticompetitive practices of <strong>in</strong>putsuppliers of goods and services, unshackl<strong>in</strong>g entry barriers etc. For more onthis, please see: http://www.cuts-<strong>in</strong>ternational.org/pdf/Viewpo<strong>in</strong>t-CompeRegBus<strong>in</strong>essWelfare.pdf .In <strong>Vietnam</strong>, there is, however a strong political will, but lack of a strong civilsociety movement, which we are try<strong>in</strong>g to build up through support from variousdevelopment partners and the government itself.I would also recommend that readers/users of this toolkit should have a lookat an almanac that we have produced which takes stock of competition regimesaround the world at www.competitionregimes.com. This would be of greathelp to readers to see how competition laws have evolved <strong>in</strong> over 100jurisdictions and thus give an <strong>in</strong>sightful comparative picture.In many countries, new competition laws have been enacted after scrapp<strong>in</strong>golder ones, as it became irrelevant due to changes <strong>in</strong> the national and globaleconomies. These <strong>in</strong>clude UK, South Africa and India. CUTS is currentlyengaged <strong>in</strong> another project to map out the causes and reasons as to why manycountries are enact<strong>in</strong>g new competition laws after scrapp<strong>in</strong>g their old ones,which can educate all of us on the reasons for the metamorphosis. However,this change which is tak<strong>in</strong>g place <strong>in</strong> many countries confirms the fact that acompetition law is desirable and it needs to be updated as we move along <strong>in</strong>history.In our experience, a new competition law has to be implemented graduallyrather than with a bang, i.e. to say the authority has to run a marathon and nota spr<strong>in</strong>t. It is, therefore, that we have evolved a matrix for different stages ofimplementation of competition regimes (please see Table 1 on page 87).Creat<strong>in</strong>g a healthy competition culture depends on effective implementationof the competition law and a supportive policy environment.How does a competition law help the country’s economy? There are fewsystematic studies done <strong>in</strong> Peru and South Korea, which have shown that theiv<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


law has generated far greater benefits than the cost itself. In a study of thePeruvian competition agency, Indecopi, found that the first seven years of itsoperation yielded economic benefits amount<strong>in</strong>g to US$120mn, which issignificantly higher than the associated operat<strong>in</strong>g costs of US$20mn. 1 A studyby the Korean Fair Trade Commission (KFTC) <strong>in</strong> 2003 found that the benefit(consumer welfare <strong>in</strong>creases and <strong>in</strong>come transfers) outweighed the costs(KFTC’s budget) of competition law enforcement <strong>in</strong> 2000 and 2001 by 34times 2 .A study carried out on the Australian economy estimated the expected benefitsfrom a package of competition-promot<strong>in</strong>g and deregulatory reforms (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gimprovements <strong>in</strong> the competition rules) would create annual ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> real grossdomestic product (GDP) of about 5.5 percent, or AU$23bn (US$20bn), ofwhich consumers would ga<strong>in</strong> by almost AU$9bn (US$7.96bn) – <strong>in</strong> addition to<strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> real wages, employment and government revenue 3 .In terms of acknowledgement, we must thank the Swiss State of EconomicAffairs, who have supported this publication, and Kenneth Davidson, formerlywith US Fair Trade Commission, to have commented extensively on the draftand helped us to develop this toolkit.F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>in</strong> conclusion, let us reiterate that a competition regime and itsimplementation is dynamic. Hence, this toolkit should be considered as such,rather than a f<strong>in</strong>al word. Readers are <strong>in</strong>vited to share their views atc-cier@cuts.org.Pradeep S MehtaSecretary General1 See Caceres, A (2000), “Indecopi’s first seven years” <strong>in</strong> Beatriz Boza, ed., The Role of theState <strong>in</strong> <strong>Competition</strong> and IP Policy <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America: towards an academic audit ofIndecopi, Lima.2 Chapter on Korea by Joseph Seon Hur <strong>in</strong> <strong>Competition</strong> Regimes <strong>in</strong> the World — A CivilSociety Report, Pradeep S Mehta (Ed), CUTS and INCSOC, 20063 http://www.unctad.org/en/docs//c2em_d10.en.pdf<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>v


ACRONYMSACCC : Australian <strong>Competition</strong> & <strong>Consumer</strong> CommissionAIOCD : All India Organisation of Chemists and DruggistsAPCMA : All Pakistan Cement Manufacturers AssociationBTAs : Bilateral Trade AgreementsCAD : <strong>Competition</strong> Adm<strong>in</strong>istration DepartmentCOL : Ceylon Oxygen LtdCOPRA : <strong>Consumer</strong> Protection Act of IndiaCSOs : Civil Society OrganisationsDoJ : Department of JusticeEC : European CommissionEU : European UnionEULA : End-User License AgreementFDI : Foreign Direct InvestmentFTC : Federal Trade CommissionGDP : Gross Domestic ProductHLL : H<strong>in</strong>dustan Lever LimitedIBC : International Broadcast<strong>in</strong>g CorporationICN : International <strong>Competition</strong> NetworkIGL : Industrial Gases (Pvt) LtdIPRs : Intellectual Property RightsITP : Independent Television Publications LimitedKFTC : Korea Fair Trade CommissionLPG : Liquefied Petroleum GasM&As : Mergers & AcquisitionsMCA : Monopoly Control AuthorityMCOT : Mass Communication Organisation of ThailandMDGs : Millennium Development GoalsMLM : Multi-level Market<strong>in</strong>gMNC : Mult<strong>in</strong>ational Corporation<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>vii


MRTPC : Monopolies and Restrictive TradePractices CommissionNUPH-HCM : National University Publish<strong>in</strong>g House ofHo Chi M<strong>in</strong>h CityOECD : Organisation for Economic Cooperation andDevelopmentOEMs : Equipment ManufacturersPC/OS : Personal Computer Operat<strong>in</strong>g SystemRBPs : Restrictive Bus<strong>in</strong>ess PracticesRTE : Radio Telefis EireannRTPs : Restrictive Trade PracticesSMEs : Small and Medium-sized EnterprisesSoEs : State-owned EnterprisesTNCs : Transnational CompaniesTOMCO : Tata Oil Mills CompanyTRIPs : Trade Related Aspects of IntellectualProperty RightsUBC : United Broadcast<strong>in</strong>g CorporationUTPs : Unfair Trade PracticesUTV : United Television NetworkVINASTAS : <strong>Vietnam</strong> Standards and <strong>Consumer</strong>s AssociationVNPT : <strong>Vietnam</strong> Posts and TelecommunicationsGeneral CorporationWB : The World BankWIPO : World Intellectual Property OrganisationWTO : World Trade Organisationviii<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


1. INTRODUCTION<strong>Vietnam</strong> has ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed a relatively strong macroeconomic performance overthe past 15 years. The Gross Domestic Product (GDP) expanded at a high andstable rate, averaged at around seven percent per annum, mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Vietnam</strong> oneof the fastest grow<strong>in</strong>g economies <strong>in</strong> the world.The country’s high economic growth is also accompanied by macroeconomicstability <strong>in</strong> terms of low <strong>in</strong>flation, small budget deficit, sound credit growth,and manageable external debts. International trade volumes have gone uprapidly. <strong>Vietnam</strong>’s trade-GDP-ratio is among the highest <strong>in</strong> the world. Thecurrent deficit is at the controllable level and f<strong>in</strong>anced by a considerable <strong>in</strong>crease<strong>in</strong> capital <strong>in</strong>flows, especially the foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestment (FDI). As a result,there has been no strong fluctuation <strong>in</strong> the exchange rate. Economic growthhelped to implement the social objectives and aided considerable progressestoward the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs).The above achievements are attributed to the successful implementation of acomprehensive programme of economic reform called Doi Moi that waslaunched <strong>in</strong> 1986. Before this landmark, <strong>Vietnam</strong> followed the developmentmodel of a centrally planned economy, which was characterised by a significantlevel of State <strong>in</strong>tervention <strong>in</strong> the operations of the market. In such an economicsett<strong>in</strong>g, markets were underdeveloped and the concept of “competition” wasnot even officially accepted. The economic reform programme started <strong>in</strong> 1986has <strong>in</strong>troduced a series of stabilis<strong>in</strong>g and restructur<strong>in</strong>g economic measures fortransform<strong>in</strong>g the economy from centrally planned to a market-based one.However, the advantages of a market economy have not yet been fully exploited<strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> because of flank<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions and because regulations for thesmooth operation of the markets rema<strong>in</strong> absent or <strong>in</strong>complete. Monopolisticstructure still exists <strong>in</strong> some key sectors, while restrictive bus<strong>in</strong>ess practices(RBPs) and unfair trade practices (UTPs) are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly rampant and yetbe<strong>in</strong>g effectively dealt with. An effective competition law is hence the answerto these problems.On December 03, 2004, the XI th National Assembly of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, <strong>in</strong> its 6 th session,passed a <strong>Law</strong> on <strong>Competition</strong>, which came <strong>in</strong>to effect <strong>in</strong> July 2005, and hasbeen adm<strong>in</strong>istered s<strong>in</strong>ce then by the <strong>Competition</strong> Adm<strong>in</strong>istration Department(CAD) of the M<strong>in</strong>istry of Trade of <strong>Vietnam</strong>.The adoption of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> 2004 together with other related rulesand regulations exhibits the Government’s commitment to ensure a fair and<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 1


INTRODUCTIONcompetitive trad<strong>in</strong>g environment <strong>in</strong> the economy. However, there are challenges,which <strong>in</strong>clude the enormously difficult task of putt<strong>in</strong>g the law <strong>in</strong>to force.This paper, researched and compiled by CUTS and customised <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Vietnam</strong>context, is meant to provide a simple and concise handbook on variousimplementation issues surround<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004. It provides thedef<strong>in</strong>itions, characteristics of and ways to deal with all the major RBPs andUTPs, which are prevalent <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Vietnam</strong> markets currently, with real-lifecase studies. Wherever possible, similar cases from other develop<strong>in</strong>g countrieshave also been cited <strong>in</strong> the text, which can help the reader understand theissues through case studies.Last but not the least, the paper will analyse the constra<strong>in</strong>ts and challenges thatthe competition authority of <strong>Vietnam</strong> may face towards build<strong>in</strong>g a healthycompetition culture <strong>in</strong> the country, and suggest a desired framework for thesame.The paper is meant for competition authority officials and adm<strong>in</strong>istrators.However, it can also be used by activists, journalists, and academics, etc. as anadvocacy tool, and by the bus<strong>in</strong>ess community for compliance education andself-regulation. Last of all, it can also be used for enhanc<strong>in</strong>g the understand<strong>in</strong>gon competition issues of other stakeholder groups <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> the matter.An Overview of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>The <strong>Law</strong> applies to all bus<strong>in</strong>ess enterprises and professional and tradeassociations <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>; overseas enterprises and associations registered <strong>in</strong><strong>Vietnam</strong>; public utilities and state monopoly enterprises; and stateadm<strong>in</strong>istrative bodies. It has supersed<strong>in</strong>g power over all other enacted laws of<strong>Vietnam</strong> regard<strong>in</strong>g RBPs and UTPs.Two State authorities are to be established for the <strong>Law</strong>’s implementation – the<strong>Competition</strong> Adm<strong>in</strong>istration Department (with <strong>in</strong>vestigative powers), with<strong>in</strong>the M<strong>in</strong>istry of Trade of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, and the <strong>Competition</strong> Council (withadjudicative powers).The <strong>Law</strong> prohibits five broad types of anticompetitive practices:• agreements that substantially restrict competition (Article 8);• abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ant or monopoly position (Article 13 & 14);• ‘concentrations of economic power’ that substantially restrict competition(Article 18);• acts of unhealthy competition (Article 39); and• anticompetitive behaviour/decisions by officials or State adm<strong>in</strong>istrativeagencies, tak<strong>in</strong>g advantage of their authority (Article 120).2 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Anticompetitive agreements <strong>in</strong>clude price fix<strong>in</strong>g, market shar<strong>in</strong>g, restrict<strong>in</strong>goutput, block<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestment or technological development; impos<strong>in</strong>g coercivecontract<strong>in</strong>g conditions on other enterprises; restrict<strong>in</strong>g entries; exclud<strong>in</strong>g/foreclos<strong>in</strong>g non-members from the market; and bid rigg<strong>in</strong>g.Except for the last three, which are considered to be violations <strong>in</strong> all cases,other agreements are prohibited only if the parties to the agreements hold acomb<strong>in</strong>ed market share of at least 30 percent of the relevant market.The competition authorities will have the discretionary powers to grantexemptions where they consider that an anticompetitive agreement’s harm tothe economy and to the competitive process is outweighed by its potentialbenefits with regards to corporate restructur<strong>in</strong>g, technological advances,<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the competitiveness of small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs),and <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the competitiveness of <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese firms <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternationalmarkets, etc. (Article 10). Exemptions are available only if the enterprisesapply for an exemption and could prove that they are entitled to the exemption.INTRODUCTIONThe <strong>Law</strong> provides for a collective market dom<strong>in</strong>ant position of firms hav<strong>in</strong>g atotal market share of 50 percent (for two bus<strong>in</strong>ess entities); 65 percent (forthree); and 75 percent (for four) of the relevant market (Article 11). A dom<strong>in</strong>antmarket position would apply to firms hold<strong>in</strong>g at least a 30 percent marketshare, or firms that are ‘capable of substantially restrict<strong>in</strong>g competition’.Dom<strong>in</strong>ant firms are prohibited from undertak<strong>in</strong>g predatory behaviours withthe <strong>in</strong>tent of driv<strong>in</strong>g out competitors, discrim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g amongst different firmsfor the same transaction, block<strong>in</strong>g entry, and engag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> ‘other practices’ <strong>in</strong>restra<strong>in</strong>t of competition as stipulated by law, etc. (Article 13).A monopoly market position would be deemed to apply to a firm if it has nocompetitors for goods it trades or for services it provides (Article 12).Monopoly firms are prevented from undertak<strong>in</strong>g any of the abusive behaviourslisted <strong>in</strong> the previous paragraph perta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g to dom<strong>in</strong>ant firms, as well asimpos<strong>in</strong>g disadvantageous conditions on consumers; unilaterally resc<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gor replac<strong>in</strong>g a contract with legitimate reasons; refus<strong>in</strong>g to transact with ordiscrim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g aga<strong>in</strong>st a customer without legitimate reason; and any otherprohibited practice stipulated by law (Article 14).Economic concentration activities are def<strong>in</strong>ed as any conduct by a firm thataims to govern the activities of other enterprises, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g, but notlimited to, mergers, acquisitions and consolidations that have this aim(Article 16-17).All concentration cases <strong>in</strong> which the comb<strong>in</strong>ed market share of the relevantfirms would be 50 percent or more are prohibited except where, (1) the resultis still a small or medium-sized enterprise (a concept not def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the law) or(2) the Prime M<strong>in</strong>ister grants an exemption (Article 18-19).<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 3


INTRODUCTIONA 30-day notification to the competition authorities is mandatory where theparticipat<strong>in</strong>g parties would have a comb<strong>in</strong>ed market share of 30-50 percent.As regard acts of unhealthy competition, the <strong>Law</strong> prohibits: falsification ofcommercial <strong>in</strong>structions; <strong>in</strong>fr<strong>in</strong>gement of bus<strong>in</strong>ess secrets; acts of bribery,<strong>in</strong>ducement or coercion; defamation of other enterprises; disrupt<strong>in</strong>g the lawfulbus<strong>in</strong>ess practices of other firms; advertisements and promotions aimed atunhealthy competition; discrim<strong>in</strong>ation with<strong>in</strong> or by an <strong>in</strong>dustry association;and illegal multi-level (pyramid) sell<strong>in</strong>g of goods (Article 39).The <strong>Law</strong> also stipulates detailed rules and procedures govern<strong>in</strong>g compla<strong>in</strong>ts,<strong>in</strong>vestigations, <strong>in</strong>terim orders by the competition authorities, consideration ofalleged abuses, and penalties thereof. Either an affected party or the CAD can<strong>in</strong>itiate a case, and where the Department determ<strong>in</strong>es that it has jurisdictionover an external compla<strong>in</strong>t (with<strong>in</strong> seven days from receipt of compla<strong>in</strong>t), itmust beg<strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>vestigation.In proven cases of breach of the <strong>Law</strong>, the competition authorities can imposef<strong>in</strong>es of up to 10 percent of turnover of the previous f<strong>in</strong>ancial year of thealleged parties; issue warn<strong>in</strong>gs; revoke legal permits or certificates; confiscatephysical proof or means used to carry out the breach; require restructur<strong>in</strong>g offirms or contracts; or take any other coercive measures to remedy the <strong>in</strong>flictedharm.For download<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Vietnam</strong> <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>, please visit:http://www.cuts-ccier.org/pdf/CLDC-<strong>Vietnam</strong>.pdf4 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


2. ABOUT THE MARKET ECONOMY2.1. Markets and Prices – How they Work?In the bus<strong>in</strong>ess or economics world, the term ‘market’ isusually used to refer to a mechanism which allows peopleto trade, which is normally governed by the theory ofsupply and demand, so allocat<strong>in</strong>g resources through aprice mechanism and bid and ask match<strong>in</strong>g so that thosewill<strong>in</strong>g to pay a price for someth<strong>in</strong>g meet those will<strong>in</strong>gto sell for it. 1Market = Products/Services + Suppliers+ Customerswww.sxc.huDemand and supply are affected by various factors, for example, demand isaffected by changes <strong>in</strong> the prices of related goods, changes <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, tastes,population or expectations, etc; whereas supply is affected by changes <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>putprices, changes <strong>in</strong> technology, number of suppliers, etc. In a simplifiedeconomics model, the demand and the supply curve can be put together todescribe market behaviours. 2As a general rule, markets move toward equilibrium, a situation <strong>in</strong> which no<strong>in</strong>dividual will be better off tak<strong>in</strong>g a different action. In the case of a competitivemarket, we can be more specific: a competitive market is <strong>in</strong> equilibrium whenthe price has moved to a level at which the quantity demanded of a good equalsthe quantity supplied of that good. At that price, no <strong>in</strong>dividual seller couldmake herself better off by offer<strong>in</strong>g to sell either more or less of the good andno <strong>in</strong>dividual buyer could make himself better off by offer<strong>in</strong>g to buy more orless of the good.The price that matches the quantity supplied and the quantity demanded is theequilibrium price, which is also known as the market-clear<strong>in</strong>g price – theprice that ‘clears the market’ by ensur<strong>in</strong>g that every buyer will<strong>in</strong>g to pay thatprice f<strong>in</strong>ds a seller will<strong>in</strong>g to sell at that price, and vice versa.There are some markets where the same good can sell for many different prices,depend<strong>in</strong>g on who is sell<strong>in</strong>g or who is buy<strong>in</strong>g. For example, have you everbought a souvenir <strong>in</strong> a tourists’ shop and then seen the same item on salesomewhere else (perhaps even the next store) for a lower price? But <strong>in</strong> anymarket where the buyers and sellers have both been around for sometime,sales and purchases tend to converge at a generally uniformed price, so that wecan safely talk about the market price. This is easy to understand. Suppose a<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 5


ABOUT THE MARKET ECONOMYseller offered a potential buyer a price noticeably above what the buyer knewother people to be pay<strong>in</strong>g. The buyer would clearly be better off shopp<strong>in</strong>gelsewhere – unless the seller was prepared to offer a better deal. Conversely, aseller would not be will<strong>in</strong>g to sell for significantly less than the amount heknew most buyers were pay<strong>in</strong>g; he would be better off wait<strong>in</strong>g to get a morereasonable customer. So <strong>in</strong> any well-established, active market, all sellersreceive and all buyers pay approximately the same price – which is called themarket price. If this price is above its equilibrium level, there will be a surplusthat drives the price down. Similarly, if the price is below its equilibrium level,there is a shortage that drives the price up.This is what essentially happens <strong>in</strong> a market economy, steered primarily bymarket forces, which allocate resources, presumably scarce, and goods anddeterm<strong>in</strong>e prices. A market economy, thus, is different from a centrally plannedeconomy, one such as <strong>in</strong> existence <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> before the reform process started<strong>in</strong> 1986, <strong>in</strong> that the aggregate <strong>in</strong>teractions of buyers and sellers, producers andconsumers <strong>in</strong> a society determ<strong>in</strong>e how different markets work <strong>in</strong> a marketeconomy, whereas <strong>in</strong> a centrally planned system, this is decided byadm<strong>in</strong>istrative decisions made by government bureaus.2.2. Governments and the Rule of <strong>Law</strong> vs Free MarketsIn the simplified model above, we have considered only two ma<strong>in</strong> actors of themarketplace, which are buyers and sellers, or consumers and producers. In alleconomies, whether follower of a system based on market forces or centrallyplanned, the governments’ role is someth<strong>in</strong>g which cannot be ignored.Governments can act as providers of public goods, or producers of many othergoods and services. More important is their role as regulators. This is becausemarkets left to its own have a lot of <strong>in</strong>efficiencies.A market economy isdifferent from a centrallyplanned economy, onesuch as <strong>in</strong> existence <strong>in</strong><strong>Vietnam</strong> before thereform process started<strong>in</strong> 1986.There are many causes of market <strong>in</strong>efficiencies.Commonly observed causes of market<strong>in</strong>efficiencies <strong>in</strong>clude monopoly power,externalities such as pollution, <strong>in</strong>formationasymmetry, uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, and various forms ofopportunistic/strategic behaviours. Thegovernments can enforce laws and regulations,provide public goods, or obta<strong>in</strong> and dissem<strong>in</strong>ate<strong>in</strong>formation effectively.Unfortunately, <strong>in</strong> many cases, the governments go beyond their role asregulators, or providers of public goods and services. Arbitrary <strong>in</strong>terventionsor over-<strong>in</strong>tervention <strong>in</strong>to the normal operations of the markets, favouritismover state-owned enterprises (SoEs), etc. are typically such <strong>in</strong>stances. It is,therefore, important to make sure that the rule of law prevails.The rule of law has two ma<strong>in</strong> economic functions. First, it regulates and limitsdiscretionary <strong>in</strong>terventions of the state <strong>in</strong>to economic activities. Secondly, it6 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


egulates the economic behaviour of <strong>in</strong>dividuals and enterprises to create anorderly, stable environment with fair competition, clearly def<strong>in</strong>ed and wellprotected property rights, and effectively enforced contracts. 3The situation <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>, despite the variousreforms undertaken s<strong>in</strong>ce 1986, is far fromthis ideal model. The legal framework is yetto be completed; regulatory <strong>in</strong>stitutionsrema<strong>in</strong> absent or are at an <strong>in</strong>fant stage.Understand<strong>in</strong>g of the markets and how theywork is still ta<strong>in</strong>ted by the long history of aplanned economy, as well as an agriculturebasedeconomy. Politicians and policy-makersare still sceptical of the private sector; hencethe state sector still enjoys overwhelm<strong>in</strong>gadvantages and favours. A large <strong>in</strong>formalCommonly observedcauses of market<strong>in</strong>efficiencies <strong>in</strong>cludemonopoly power,externalities such aspollution, <strong>in</strong>formationasymmetry, uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty,and various forms ofopportunistic/strategicbehaviours.economy is <strong>in</strong> place, <strong>in</strong>formation is lack<strong>in</strong>g, database absent, mak<strong>in</strong>g the taskof fair economic regulation all the more difficult.ABOUT THE MARKET ECONOMY<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 7


3. MARKET AND COMPETITION3.1. <strong>Competition</strong>In an idealised model, market [or bus<strong>in</strong>ess]competition is a process of rivalry by whichproducers/suppliers strive to offer the mostattractive price and quality options to ga<strong>in</strong> newsales, and new clientele.As already mentioned <strong>in</strong> Chaper 2: About theMarket Economy, there are several factorswhich affect the consumption and supply decisions by consumers and producers<strong>in</strong> a free market. Demand by consumers, for example, is affected by price, i.e.if the price goes up, the quantity demanded goes down. As bread becomesmore expensive, consumers turn to other goods, perhaps buy<strong>in</strong>g more muff<strong>in</strong>sor sweet rolls <strong>in</strong>stead. Similarly, demand for a certa<strong>in</strong> good or service byconsumers is under the <strong>in</strong>fluence of their <strong>in</strong>come level, prices of related goodsand their tastes. Supply decisions by producers are also affected by price.Typically, it is reasonable to assume that the higher the price per loaf of bread,the greater the quantity that firms are will<strong>in</strong>g to supply, s<strong>in</strong>ce higher pricesmake it profitable for firms to produce more output. Similarly, supply is affectedby price of <strong>in</strong>puts, and conditions of production, etc.Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, <strong>in</strong> a competitive market, where there are a wide range of productsand services, which are substitutable for each other, available <strong>in</strong> the market atacceptable prices, consumers can always shift purchase to a more competitiveproduct/service, which <strong>in</strong>duces producers to compete with each other to satisfy<strong>Competition</strong> is a naturaltrend between variousproducers, of same orrelated products, <strong>in</strong>terms of price, quality. orafter-sale services, etc.most notably throughprices.8 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>consumer preferences. Therefore, competition isa natural trend between various producers, of sameor related products, <strong>in</strong> terms of price, quality, orafter-sale services, etc. most notably throughprices. 4 However, <strong>in</strong> fact, there may be differentscenarios, for <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong> case of a monopoly;there is only one producer/provider of a certa<strong>in</strong>good and service <strong>in</strong> a market, with no substitute,which gives the only market player power beyondany market discipl<strong>in</strong>e.For example, Big C, Metro and Intimex are three supermarket cha<strong>in</strong>s currentlyoperat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Hanoi. They all sell similar products, such as food, cloth<strong>in</strong>g, toys,etc. or products which are substitutable for each other, such as burgers andsandwiches, Coca Cola and Sprite or Nestle iced tea. They, therefore, have towww.images.com


compete for the patronage of customers/consumers <strong>in</strong> Hanoi by offer<strong>in</strong>g lowerprices, better choices, provid<strong>in</strong>g better and faster cashier services, etc.3.2. Relevant Market<strong>Competition</strong> is not homogeneous <strong>in</strong> all markets.Two supermarkets <strong>in</strong> Hanoi compete with eachother for customers <strong>in</strong> Hanoi, and not Ho ChiM<strong>in</strong>h City. Or two mobile service providerscompete with each other to provide better phoneservice and not postal service. <strong>Competition</strong>between these bus<strong>in</strong>esses also varies accord<strong>in</strong>gto time, for example, competition between twobeer producers <strong>in</strong> summer, or dur<strong>in</strong>g the WorldCup Championship, will be fiercer than <strong>in</strong> w<strong>in</strong>ter.‘Relevant Market’ is the first and foremostconcept to understand any competition analyses.‘Relevant Market’ identifies the extent of effective competitive constra<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong>the market, <strong>in</strong> terms of product/services, time and location. 5 To def<strong>in</strong>e therelevant market for a particular competition case, one usually looks at the‘Product Market’ and the ‘GeographicMarket’ <strong>in</strong> a specific ‘Period of Time’.‘Relevant Market’ is thefirst and foremostconcept to understand <strong>in</strong>almost any competitionanalyses, whichidentifies the extent ofeffective competitiveconstra<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> themarket, <strong>in</strong> terms ofproduct/services, timeand location.Product Market: A Product Market<strong>in</strong>cludes all products that are closesubstitutes for one another – both <strong>in</strong>consumption and production. 6In a simple example, one might attemptto determ<strong>in</strong>e if Glass Bottles are <strong>in</strong> thesame product market as Plastic Bottles.In this scenario, one looks to see if thisGlass Bottle price <strong>in</strong>crease leads tosignificant changes <strong>in</strong> the consumptionpatterns of both the two types of conta<strong>in</strong>ers. If, <strong>in</strong> response to the price <strong>in</strong>crease,consumers switch a sufficient volume of Glass Bottle purchases to PlasticBottles, then Plastic Bottles would be considered to be with<strong>in</strong> the same productmarket as Glass Bottles.www.google.comMARKET AND COMPETITIONGeographic Market: A Geographic Market, similarly, is determ<strong>in</strong>ed on thebasis of customers’ or consumers’ ability to switch purchase between suppliersof substitute products <strong>in</strong> case of a price hike. If the airfare between Ho ChiM<strong>in</strong>h City and Phnom Penh (Cambodia) provided by <strong>Vietnam</strong> Airl<strong>in</strong>es is<strong>in</strong>creased, and passengers are able to switch to travell<strong>in</strong>g by Air Cambodia orThai Airways International with least <strong>in</strong>convenience, then all these airl<strong>in</strong>es,though based <strong>in</strong> different countries, can be considered as compet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> onegeographic market, namely the Ho Chi M<strong>in</strong>h-Phnom Penh route.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 9


MARKET AND COMPETITIONIn another case, even if it is otherwise convenient for a buyer to purchase a carfrom S<strong>in</strong>gapore, the heavy import duty <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> works as a dis<strong>in</strong>centive forthe <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese consumers to buy a car from outside <strong>Vietnam</strong>. Therefore, fromthe viewpo<strong>in</strong>t of <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese car users, <strong>Vietnam</strong> is their geographic market.In addition to import duties and explicitly protectionist measures, there areother factors, such as regulations protect<strong>in</strong>g health and safety, or licens<strong>in</strong>grequirements, or shipp<strong>in</strong>g costs, which establish barriers to competition, andthus, help def<strong>in</strong>e geographic markets. 7Relevant markets, therefore, are usually def<strong>in</strong>ed from the po<strong>in</strong>t of view ofconsumers. A simple example for relevant market would therefore be, to say:“Company A and Company B are competitors <strong>in</strong> the market for telephoneservices (mobile, fixed l<strong>in</strong>e, satellite, etc) <strong>in</strong> Hanoi”.The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> (also referred to here<strong>in</strong>after as ‘the<strong>Law</strong>’) def<strong>in</strong>es relevant market to be ‘relevant market of products and relevantgeographic market’; <strong>in</strong> which ‘relevant market of products means a market ofgoods, services which are <strong>in</strong>terchangeable <strong>in</strong> terms of characteristics, usepurposes and prices’; and ‘relevant geographic market means a specificgeographical area <strong>in</strong> which goods exist, services which are <strong>in</strong>terchangeableunder similar conditions of competition, and which is considerablydifferentiated from neighbour<strong>in</strong>g areas’. 8Further, the Decree No. 116/2005/ND-CP issued by the Government of <strong>Vietnam</strong>for detailed guidel<strong>in</strong>es on the <strong>Law</strong>’s implementation (here<strong>in</strong>after referred to asthe Decree 116/2005) also provides for several factors to be taken <strong>in</strong>toconsideration while def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g relevant product and geographic markets,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g substitutability of products (Article 4 of the Decree), market structureand practices of consumers, market for products auxiliary to the relevant product(Article 5 of the Decree), capability of substitution <strong>in</strong> terms of supply (Article6 of the Decree), competitive conditions and barriers to market access (Article7 & 8 of the Decree). <strong>Consumer</strong> surveys might also be used dur<strong>in</strong>g the process(Article 4(5) of the Decree). 9This is very much <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the common concept of relevant market andcommon method of relevant market def<strong>in</strong>ition. However, it might be quiteresource-<strong>in</strong>tensive for a young competition regime like <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>, which needsmore human resources, not to mention other resources like f<strong>in</strong>ance, time, etc.Besides, the problems of <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry and scarcity of data can alsoimpose serious constra<strong>in</strong>ts.Time Period: A third possible dimension to market def<strong>in</strong>ition is time. Examplesof how the tim<strong>in</strong>g of production and purchas<strong>in</strong>g can affect markets <strong>in</strong>clude: 10lPeak and off peak services: This can be a factor <strong>in</strong> transport services orutilities such as electricity supply.10 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


lllSeasonal variations, such as summer vs w<strong>in</strong>ter months: This might havesignificant implication on the purchas<strong>in</strong>g pattern of consumers when it comesto such goods as cloth<strong>in</strong>g, air-conditioners or heaters, etc.Innovation/<strong>in</strong>ter-generational products: Customers may defer expenditureon present products because they believe <strong>in</strong>novation will soon producebetter products or because they own an earlier version of the product, whichthey consider to be a close substitute for the current generation. Someexamples are trendy garments, or computer software, etc.Possibility of new entry <strong>in</strong> the future: In addition to those producers whohave already supplied the market (on the assumption they will do so <strong>in</strong> thefuture), some others can and would supply the market <strong>in</strong> response to ananticompetitive action.To some extent, the time dimension is simply an extension of the productdimension: i.e., the product can be def<strong>in</strong>ed as the supply of tra<strong>in</strong> services at acerta<strong>in</strong> time of day.The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, while def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the relevant markets,does not mention the time dimension. However, Article 6 of the Decree 116/2005 does touch upon this when tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account factors such as “durationof supply of goods or services onto the market when there is a sudden <strong>in</strong>crease<strong>in</strong> demand”, or “use duration of the goods or services”, or “ability to replacesupply”. Notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g this, the future dimension rema<strong>in</strong>s unclear.MARKET AND COMPETITION3.3. Market Share & StructureMarket share, <strong>in</strong> strategic management and market<strong>in</strong>g, is the percentage orproportion of the total available market or market segment that is be<strong>in</strong>g servicedby a company. 11 In the competition world, market share of a company willvary accord<strong>in</strong>g to the def<strong>in</strong>ition of relevant markets. The smaller the relevantmarket def<strong>in</strong>ed for a particular case, the higher share a company may accountfor <strong>in</strong> that market.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of<strong>Vietnam</strong>, ‘an enterprise’s market share of certa<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>d of goods or service means the percentagebetween sale turnover of this enterprise andaggregate turnover of all enterprises deal<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>such k<strong>in</strong>d of goods or service on the relevantmarket or the percentage between purchaseturnover of this enterprise and aggregate purchaseturnover of all enterprises deal<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> such k<strong>in</strong>d ofgoods or service on the relevant market on amonthly, quarterly or yearly basis’. 12Market share, <strong>in</strong> strategicmanagement andmarket<strong>in</strong>g, is thepercentage or proportionof the total availablemarket or marketsegment that is be<strong>in</strong>gserviced by a company.In economics, markets are classified accord<strong>in</strong>g to the structure of the <strong>in</strong>dustryserv<strong>in</strong>g the market. Industry structure is categorised on the basis of marketstructure variables which are believed to determ<strong>in</strong>e the extent and characteristics<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 11


MARKET AND COMPETITIONwww.bized.co.ukof competition there<strong>in</strong>. Those variables which are most popular are the numberof buyers and sellers, the extent of product substitutability, costs, ease of entryand exit, and the extent of mutual <strong>in</strong>terdependence. In the traditional framework,these structural variables are distilled <strong>in</strong>to the follow<strong>in</strong>g taxonomy of marketstructures:Perfect competition: A market structure <strong>in</strong> which all firms produce ahomogeneous, perfectly divisible output; producers and consumers have full<strong>in</strong>formation, <strong>in</strong>cur transaction costs and are price takers; and there are noexternalities. 13 S<strong>in</strong>ce perfect competition is rarely, if ever, encountered <strong>in</strong> thereal world, it is mentioned here only as an ideal aga<strong>in</strong>st which to compareother types of market structures.Normal competition: A market structure <strong>in</strong> which a large number of firmscompete with each other by mak<strong>in</strong>g similar but slightly different products. 14Each of the firm has some control over the prices it charges s<strong>in</strong>ce products are12 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


differentiated. However, s<strong>in</strong>ce there are no significant barriers to entry andproducts are closely substitutable, the firm cannot affect the market as a whole.Such market structure is often referred to as ‘normal’ or ‘workable competition’.Many markets can be cited as examples hereby, for example, the markets forbooks, cloth<strong>in</strong>g, films and service <strong>in</strong>dustries <strong>in</strong> large cities.Oligopoly: A market structure <strong>in</strong> which the market is dom<strong>in</strong>ated by a smallnumber of sellers or buyers (oligopolists 15 ). Because there are few participants<strong>in</strong> this type of market, each oligopolist is aware that it can affect market priceand hence its competitors’ profits: Ford cannot and does not ignore Hondawhen mak<strong>in</strong>g decisions regard<strong>in</strong>g automobile production. Oligopolistic markets,thus, can be said as be<strong>in</strong>g characterised by <strong>in</strong>ter-relationship between marketparticipants. A firm must consider rival firms’ behaviours to determ<strong>in</strong>e its ownbest policy. The mobile phone service market <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> is an example ofoligopoly.Monopoly: This is a market structure characterised by a s<strong>in</strong>gle firm sell<strong>in</strong>g aproduct for which there are no close substitutes and by substantial barriers toentry. 16 In this case, the monopolist can maximise its profit by charg<strong>in</strong>g thehighest price the market will bear.3.4. <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> & Policy<strong>Competition</strong> has <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly been recognised as the cornerstone of thriv<strong>in</strong>geconomies throughout the world. 17 It is essential for the efficient allocation ofresources, helps to promote <strong>in</strong>novation, <strong>in</strong>creasesfactor productivity, creates more employment and<strong>in</strong>come earn<strong>in</strong>g opportunities, enables SMEs toparticipate <strong>in</strong> the market. It is thus a useful toolfor growth and poverty reduction. 18Competitive forces work best <strong>in</strong> the presence ofmarkets that are free from distortions. However,perfect competition rarely exists <strong>in</strong> real life, sothe full benefits of competition do not oftenmaterialise. 19 The competitive process is more than often discouraged and isnot fair for reasons of special <strong>in</strong>terests, big government, and citizens’ weakeconomic understand<strong>in</strong>g. Whenmarkets are not competitive, whetherdue to policy-<strong>in</strong>duced distortions,technological characteristics, oranticompetitive behaviour by marketparticipants, an economy may missmany potential benefits for its citizens.Furthermore, government deregulationefforts that are <strong>in</strong>tended to benefitwww.images.com<strong>Competition</strong> policy refersto those governmentmeasures that directlyaffect the behaviour offirms and the structureof the <strong>in</strong>dustry.consumers might even have countereffects.MARKET AND COMPETITION<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 13


MARKET AND COMPETITIONConsequently, <strong>in</strong> addition to discipl<strong>in</strong>es to elim<strong>in</strong>ate non-competitive behavioursby market participants, other measures are needed to enforce policies thatencourage firms to compete (or discourage or prevent firms from resist<strong>in</strong>grivalry), <strong>in</strong> order to improve the efficient allocation of resources. Thus, thebenefits from competition are not only<strong>Competition</strong> law is abody of legal rules andprovisions that ensuresfairness and freedom <strong>in</strong>the marketplace.limited to keep<strong>in</strong>g prices at marg<strong>in</strong>al costfor the benefit of consumers, as <strong>in</strong> staticefficiency, but also create a conduciveenvironment for new bus<strong>in</strong>esses to enterand grow while at the same time compelexist<strong>in</strong>g firms to cont<strong>in</strong>uously improveand perform better.<strong>Competition</strong> policy refers to those government measures that directly affectthe behaviour of firms and the structure of the <strong>in</strong>dustry. It is an <strong>in</strong>tegral part ofeconomic policy, and may embrace several elements such as trade liberalisation,<strong>in</strong>dustrial, <strong>in</strong>vestment, and privatisation policies, which have the ma<strong>in</strong> objectiveof preserv<strong>in</strong>g and promot<strong>in</strong>g competition as a means to ensure efficientallocation of resources <strong>in</strong> an economy, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the best possible choice ofquality, the lowest prices, and adequate supplies to consumers.<strong>Competition</strong> law, on the other hand, is a body of legal rules and provisions thatensures fairness and freedom <strong>in</strong> the marketplace by regulat<strong>in</strong>g the conducts offirms, prohibit<strong>in</strong>g anticompetitive arrangements and abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ance, whichimpede the competitive process and hamper the legitimate rights and <strong>in</strong>terestsof other market players, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g consumers.<strong>Competition</strong> Policy = Economic Policies Affect<strong>in</strong>g<strong>Competition</strong> + <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>14 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


4. RESTRICTIVE BUSINESSPRACTICESRestrictive bus<strong>in</strong>ess practices (RBPs), or anticompetitive practices, put simply,are actions by enterprises, whether <strong>in</strong> the private or public sector, designed tolimit access to markets or restra<strong>in</strong> competition <strong>in</strong> the market <strong>in</strong> order to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>or <strong>in</strong>crease their relative market position and profits without necessarilyprovid<strong>in</strong>g goods and services at a lower cost or of higher quality.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the word<strong>in</strong>g of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, they are‘competition-restrict<strong>in</strong>g acts […] performed by enterprises to reduce, distortand prevent competition on the market, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g enter<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to competitionrestrict<strong>in</strong>gagreements, abus<strong>in</strong>g the dom<strong>in</strong>ant position on the market, abus<strong>in</strong>gthe monopoly position and economic concentration’. 20There are various types of RBPs, each of which will be expla<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> a nutshell.Together with them there will be the relevant legal provisions and cases <strong>in</strong><strong>Vietnam</strong>, as well as quoted cases from elsewhere <strong>in</strong> the world deal<strong>in</strong>g withsuch practices.4.1. Market PowerA key concept <strong>in</strong> many competition analysesis that of ‘Market Power’. Without marketpower, no anticompetitive practices by firmscould achieve their <strong>in</strong>tended goal.‘Market power’ refers to the ability of an<strong>in</strong>dividual firm or a group of firms to raiseand ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> price above the level whichwould prevail under competition. 21 The highest degree of market power isassociated with a monopoly, although all firms; except for those operat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>perfectly competitive markets; possess some degree of market power.www.manag<strong>in</strong>gip.comHigh market share is generally considered as a necessary, though not a sufficient,condition to establish market power. 22 Besides, as debate exists on what criteriabest reflects potential market power; even the measurement of market share isa controversial issue. For example, market share can be measured by currentsales, historical sales or even capacity (potential).Some jurisdictions have established de facto or de jure benchmark marketshares above or below which market power is presumed to exist or not exist.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 15


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICES‘Market power’ refers tothe ability of an<strong>in</strong>dividual firm or a groupof firms to raise andma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> price above thelevel which would prevailunder competition.Yet, it is not clear that there is aneconomic justification for predeterm<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gthe existence of marketpower at any given market share.Alternatively, concerns aboutadm<strong>in</strong>istrative efficiency sometimesjustify a market share ‘safe harbour’,below which market power is deemed notto exist.Determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g whether a firm or group of firms have market power or not is thestart<strong>in</strong>g po<strong>in</strong>t for case analysis with regard to abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ance. (This is atype of RBPs, which would be discussed <strong>in</strong> Section 4.6). Important factors thatmust be considered <strong>in</strong> measur<strong>in</strong>g the market power of a firm or a group offirms, other than market share, <strong>in</strong>clude:l number and market shares of competitors;l nature of the relevant product;l countervail<strong>in</strong>g power of other market participants;l <strong>in</strong>tellectual property rights (IPRs);l market characteristics such as regulatory environment, rate oftechnical change, existence of potential or poised competitors; andl barriers to entry.Though be<strong>in</strong>g last <strong>in</strong> the list, barriers to entry usually constitute the mostimportant factor. Dom<strong>in</strong>ance does not exist if entry to a market is easy. A firmwith a 90 percent share of the market is not dom<strong>in</strong>ant if, as soon as it raise theprice of its goods, other firms would enter its market and sell their goods atmore competitive prices. As a result, a def<strong>in</strong>ition of dom<strong>in</strong>ance requires ananalysis of whether there are any barriers to entry.Barriers to entry may be constituted by various factors, rang<strong>in</strong>g from governmentregulation, IPRs, access to capital, considerable costs of entry, economies ofscale necessary to penetrate the market, a well-organised distribution system,advertis<strong>in</strong>g, customer loyalty and brand recognition, etc. Sometimes, barriersto entry may <strong>in</strong>clude restrictive practices by the dom<strong>in</strong>ant bus<strong>in</strong>esses alreadyoperat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the field try<strong>in</strong>g to protect their position.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, ‘enterprises shall beconsidered to hold dom<strong>in</strong>ant positions <strong>in</strong> the market if they have market sharesof 30 percent or more <strong>in</strong> the relevant market or are capable of restrict<strong>in</strong>gcompetition considerably’, whereas ‘groups of enterprises shall be consideredto hold the dom<strong>in</strong>ant position <strong>in</strong> the market if they take concerted action torestrict competition and fall <strong>in</strong>to one of the follow<strong>in</strong>g cases: (a) two enterpriseshav<strong>in</strong>g total market share of 50 percent or more <strong>in</strong> the relevant market; (b)three enterprises hav<strong>in</strong>g total market share of 65 percent or more <strong>in</strong> the relevantmarket; and (c) four enterprises hav<strong>in</strong>g total market share of 75 percent ormore <strong>in</strong> the relevant market’. 23 On the other hand, ‘an enterprise shall be16 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


considered to hold the monopoly position if there is no enterprise compet<strong>in</strong>gon the goods or services dealt <strong>in</strong> by such enterprise on the relevant market’. 24While the <strong>Law</strong> follows the usual method of def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g market dom<strong>in</strong>ance (andgroup dom<strong>in</strong>ance) on the basis of ‘market share’, it also set another filter forthe dom<strong>in</strong>ance test, which is targeted at the capability of an enterprise to restrictcompetition substantially. The Decree 116/2005 further stipulates that thiscapability will be def<strong>in</strong>ed on the basis of either the enterprise’s f<strong>in</strong>ancial strength,or its technological strength, or its IPRs and the scale of the distributionnetwork. 25 This is essentially the same as other factors that we have mentionedabove about market power and barriers to entry.4.2. Per se or Rule of Reason?RBPs as well as other conducts that impose undue restra<strong>in</strong>ts on competition,such as mergers & acquisitions (M&As) which are to be analysed subsequentlyare regulated by competition law. Such regulation, however, may entail variousapproaches.Some restra<strong>in</strong>ts are considered illegal per se <strong>in</strong> some jurisdictions. This meansthey are conclusively presumed to impose unreasonable restra<strong>in</strong>t on thecompetitive process and thus anticompetitive, 26 or can be held as illegal byitself, without further defence.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the rule ofreason, some strategicbehaviour by firms mighthave both restra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>geffects on competitionand dynamic efficiencybenefits.In other cases, it is established that onlycomb<strong>in</strong>ations and contractsunreasonably restra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g trade aresubject to actions under the competitionlaws and that size and possession ofmonopoly power were not illegal. Inthese cases, the RTPs (as well as othercompetition concerns) is said to besubject to the ‘rule of reason’.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the rule of reason, somestrategic behaviour by firms might have both restra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g effects on competitionand dynamic efficiency benefits. In case the latter consequences override theformer effects, then that behaviour could be allowed to pass the scrut<strong>in</strong>y ofcompetition statutes. A practice may be held as efficiency-enhanc<strong>in</strong>g if:(i) it can be found to be pro-competitive (for example, <strong>in</strong> promot<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>novationand technological advance, promot<strong>in</strong>g exports or the country’s <strong>in</strong>ternationalcompetitiveness, etc), or(ii) it has been undertaken <strong>in</strong> public <strong>in</strong>terests (for example, by avoid<strong>in</strong>gunemployment or protect<strong>in</strong>g the environment, etc).RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESGett<strong>in</strong>g exemption on these grounds means that an agreement is accepted to betrade-restrictive, but the ga<strong>in</strong> from it would outweigh the loss caused by itsanticompetitive nature.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 17


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESThe entire <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> requires rule of reason analysisexcept a below 30 percent “safe harbours” created for anticompetitiveagreements that would otherwise violate its Art 8 (Sections 1-5), see Section4.3 for a more detailed discussion on this. This is similar to Article 81 of theEuropean Union (EU) Treaty, which states that the prohibitions onanticompetitive agreements are per se violations <strong>in</strong> Section 2 but then provides<strong>in</strong> Section 3 that there are further defences that may make the actions of Section2 lawful. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, the entire consideration of the lawfulness or unlawfulnessof bus<strong>in</strong>ess practices <strong>in</strong>cludes the defences (or <strong>in</strong> the language of the <strong>Vietnam</strong>esecompetition law – the exemptions).The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> gives exemption (for a def<strong>in</strong>ite term)to ‘competition-restrict<strong>in</strong>g agreements’ if they meet one of the follow<strong>in</strong>gconditions <strong>in</strong> order to reduce costs to benefit consumers:l rationalis<strong>in</strong>g the organisational structure, bus<strong>in</strong>ess model, rais<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>essefficiency;l promot<strong>in</strong>g technical and technological advances, rais<strong>in</strong>g goods and servicequality;l promot<strong>in</strong>g the uniform application of quality standards and technical normsof products of different k<strong>in</strong>ds;l harmonis<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess, goods delivery and payment conditions, which haveno connection with prices and price factors;l enhanc<strong>in</strong>g the competitiveness of SMEs; andl enhanc<strong>in</strong>g the competitiveness of <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese enterprises <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternationalmarket. 27The <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g po<strong>in</strong>t is that the <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese law proclaims the RBPs listed <strong>in</strong>its Article 8 to be unlawful unless the parties have previously obta<strong>in</strong>ed anexemption. This essentially means that the bus<strong>in</strong>ess entities may not proceedwith a transaction that literally violates the prohibitions even if the transactionis pro-competitive. There may be an exception to this procedure <strong>in</strong> Art 85(d)of the Decree 116/2005 which provides that the adjudicator may treat as an“extenuat<strong>in</strong>g circumstance” proof that the violation has a “positive effect onthe economy”. This obscure provision could radically alter the clear assumptionthat the bus<strong>in</strong>esses, which would violate the competition law, must not onlyawait the decisions of the agency that can grant an exemption but also applyfor the exemption and make the application public.The requirement of a prior public request for an exemption could have hugepractical consequences. Forc<strong>in</strong>g companies to reveal their bus<strong>in</strong>ess plans couldremove much of the competitive desire to <strong>in</strong>novate. Moreover, the delay couldmake it impossible to respond to a competitive challenge from others.4.3. Anticompetitive AgreementsAgreements between competitors concern<strong>in</strong>g price, customer allocation, etc.are the RBPs that have the most obvious potential for harm<strong>in</strong>g competitionand consumers. Parties to those agreements may not be <strong>in</strong> possession of market18 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


power <strong>in</strong>dividually. However, they might enter <strong>in</strong>to an understand<strong>in</strong>g, writtenor verbal, implicit or explicit, which will help to exercise their collective marketpower <strong>in</strong> order to seek unjust economic rents for all members.Such agreements may either be betweenfirms, which are <strong>in</strong> a horizontal relationship(i.e. all parties are at the same level ofproduction or market<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a cha<strong>in</strong> to br<strong>in</strong>ga product/service to the end consumers, suchas between different producers of gas burnersor cars, or between various sellers of softdr<strong>in</strong>ks, etc), or between those, which are <strong>in</strong>a vertical relationship (i.e. one party is thesupplier of <strong>in</strong>puts to the other party’sbus<strong>in</strong>ess activity, such as distribution agreements between the manufacturersand the distributors).4.4. Horizontal Agreements among CompetitorsHorizontal anticompetitive agreements, or cartels, as they are usually called <strong>in</strong>competition jargon, have traditionally been considered the most serious of allanticompetitive practices and constitute that category of violations mostsusceptible to crim<strong>in</strong>al penalties <strong>in</strong> many jurisdictions <strong>in</strong> the world.Be<strong>in</strong>g horizontal anticompetitive agreements by nature, cartels are arrangementsbetween groups of firms that produce and sell the same product for the purposeof exact<strong>in</strong>g and shar<strong>in</strong>g monopolistic rents. Most commonly, they accomplishthis by agree<strong>in</strong>g on a relatively high common ask<strong>in</strong>g price for their productthat none of the member firms will be permitted to underbid (i.e. price-fix<strong>in</strong>gcartels). Alternatively, the member firms may simply agree to divide the marketby geographic territory or by customers and grant each other local monopolieswithout necessarily enforc<strong>in</strong>g a uniform price structure (i.e. market allocat<strong>in</strong>gor customer shar<strong>in</strong>g cartels).www.images.comRESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESCartels are considered as cancers of market economies. They are quite prevalent,rang<strong>in</strong>g from the global agreement between huge mult<strong>in</strong>ational vitam<strong>in</strong>manufacturers, to maybe the understand<strong>in</strong>g between four or five departmentalstores <strong>in</strong> a small town <strong>in</strong> Central <strong>Vietnam</strong>. Cartels are secretive by nature, andhence are very difficult to detect and <strong>in</strong>vestigate. However, it is said that<strong>in</strong>dustries or markets, which have the follow<strong>in</strong>gcharacteristics are more prone to cartelisedbehaviours:(i)Markets where there are a relatively smallnumber of firms and a large number ofcustomers;(ii) Market demand is not too variable;(iii) Products/services are generallyhomogeneous, and there are no substitutableproducts; andAgreements may eitherbe between firms, whichare <strong>in</strong> a horizontalrelationship or betweenthose, which are <strong>in</strong> avertical relationship.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 19


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICES(iv) Individual firms’ outputs, ask<strong>in</strong>g prices and sale turnovers can be easilymonitored by the cartel organisations, for example <strong>in</strong> the retail petrolmarket, where the retail prices are displayed all the times at all gas stations(so as to discourage cartel members from cheat<strong>in</strong>g and break<strong>in</strong>g up thecartel).Cartel agreements on price-fix<strong>in</strong>g, market shar<strong>in</strong>g or output restriction areforbidden under Section 1-3 of Article 8 of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of<strong>Vietnam</strong>, however, only when the comb<strong>in</strong>edHorizontalanticompetitiveagreements, or cartelshave traditionally beenconsidered the mostserious of allanticompetitivepractices and constitutethat category ofviolations mostsusceptible to crim<strong>in</strong>alpenalties <strong>in</strong> manyjurisdictions <strong>in</strong> theworld.market share of all the parties to the agreementsis 30 percent or more on the relevant market. 28This provision of a ‘safe harbour’ leads to thesignificance of def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the relevant markets aswell as assess<strong>in</strong>g market power of firms <strong>in</strong> theprocess of case analysis. If the def<strong>in</strong>ition ofmarket is too loose, the 30 percent trigger po<strong>in</strong>tfor exemption will exempt almost all agreementsother than those between oligopolists.4.4.1. Price fix<strong>in</strong>gAs mentioned before, the most common practiceundertaken by cartels is price-fix<strong>in</strong>g. This is theterm generically applied to a wide variety ofconcerted actions taken by competitors hav<strong>in</strong>ga direct effect on price. The simplest form is anagreement on the price or prices to be chargedon some or all customers. In addition to simple agreements on which price tocharge, the follow<strong>in</strong>gs are also considered price-fix<strong>in</strong>g, such agreements: 29llllllllllon price <strong>in</strong>crease;on a standard formula, accord<strong>in</strong>g to which prices will be computed;to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> a fixed ratio between the prices of compet<strong>in</strong>g but non-identicalproducts;to elim<strong>in</strong>ate discounts orto establish uniformdiscounts;on credit term what willbe extended tocustomers;to remove productsoffered at low prices fromthe market so as to limitsupply and keep prices high;not to reduce prices withoutnotify<strong>in</strong>g other cartel members;to adhere to published prices;not to sell unless agreed on price terms are met; andto use a uniform price as start<strong>in</strong>g po<strong>in</strong>t for negotiations.www.accc.gov.au20 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Box 1: Cartel of Cement Manufacturersand the Action by the MCAIn October 1998, cement manufacturers <strong>in</strong> Pakistan <strong>in</strong>creased the price of50-kg bag by Rs 100 from Rs 135/bag to Rs 235/bag. Tak<strong>in</strong>g a note of thissituation, the Monopoly Control Authority (MCA) <strong>in</strong>itiated a special enquiry<strong>in</strong>to the causes of the price <strong>in</strong>crease. The All Pakistan Cement ManufacturersAssociation (APCMA) <strong>in</strong>formed the MCA that the price <strong>in</strong>crease was dueto higher taxes and cost of <strong>in</strong>puts.However, the MCA enquiry found that there was no <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the costs of<strong>in</strong>puts, except a marg<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> electricity tariffs, whereas the level oftaxation had actually been reduced. The enquiry established that the pricewas <strong>in</strong>creased to reap undue profit, under a tacit agreement among themanufacturers through cartel formation aga<strong>in</strong>st the public <strong>in</strong>terest.The Authority passed an order to break the cartel and revert to the pricelevel which preceded the price <strong>in</strong>crease. The cement manufacturers werealso directed to deposit Rs 4.25bn, as earned through the unfair price<strong>in</strong>crease, <strong>in</strong> the Baitul Mal, so that it could be reimbursed to consumersaga<strong>in</strong>st verifiable claims. Furthermore, it imposed a f<strong>in</strong>e of Rs 100,000 oneach <strong>in</strong>dividual unit, and <strong>in</strong> case of cont<strong>in</strong>ued non-compliance, anotherRs 10,000 per day.Source: Mukhtar Ahmad Ali (2006), Pakistan, <strong>Competition</strong> Regimes <strong>in</strong> the World – A CivilSociety Report, CUTS, p.137.RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESThese are also the detailed description of the conducts by a price-fix<strong>in</strong>g cartelgiven <strong>in</strong> the Decree 116/2005. 30It is important to note, <strong>in</strong> this regard, that though price-fix<strong>in</strong>g cartels are normallydeemed as illegal per se <strong>in</strong> most jurisdictions, <strong>in</strong> the case of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, it may bepossible to establish the grounds for an exemption even for this type ofanticompetitive agreement (see Section 4.2).4.4.2. Market allocat<strong>in</strong>g and customer shar<strong>in</strong>gNext on the list are cartel agreements that divide markets by territory or bycustomers among competitors. If anyth<strong>in</strong>g, such arrangements are even morerestrictive than the most formal price-fix<strong>in</strong>g agreement, s<strong>in</strong>ce they leave noroom for competition of any k<strong>in</strong>d, and hence are often held illegal per se. This,however, is not the case <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>.In develop<strong>in</strong>g countries like <strong>Vietnam</strong>, a prevalent form of market shar<strong>in</strong>g isunspoken/unwritten understand<strong>in</strong>g between prov<strong>in</strong>cial monopolists, which hasthe same effects as cartels. A firm sell<strong>in</strong>g construction materials <strong>in</strong> Hoa B<strong>in</strong>hprov<strong>in</strong>ce may not venture to cater to the demand of a customer located <strong>in</strong> V<strong>in</strong>hPhuc prov<strong>in</strong>ce. A courier company <strong>in</strong> Hanoi may refuse to serve a consumer<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 21


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESfrom Haiphong. This conduct maynot have anyth<strong>in</strong>g to do withcollusion, and might only be an<strong>in</strong>dependent decision taken withdue consideration to bus<strong>in</strong>essefficiency, and therefore is bothlawful and strategically rational.However, the competitionauthorities should keep a watchfuleye on them, <strong>in</strong> case they are shamcovers for market allocat<strong>in</strong>gagreements.Market allocat<strong>in</strong>g and customershar<strong>in</strong>g agreements are def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>details under Article 15 of the Decree 116/2005 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, as an explanationof the prohibition towards such agreements <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004. 314.4.3. Output RestrictionUnder this agreement, enterprises produc<strong>in</strong>g/supply<strong>in</strong>g the same products/services agree to limit their supplies to a lower proportion of their previoussales. The effect of limit<strong>in</strong>g supplies is to create scarcity <strong>in</strong> the market, whichmakes it possible for sellers to raise prices of products/services. 32In <strong>Vietnam</strong>, output coord<strong>in</strong>ation has beenquite a common feature activity ofassociations between manufacturers.Justifications given <strong>in</strong>clude to avoid the‘supply-over-demand’ situation, to elim<strong>in</strong>ate‘cut-throat’ competition between smallproducers, or to reduce the level of resourceswasted, towards stabilis<strong>in</strong>g the market andbenefit<strong>in</strong>g consumers with stable prices andgood quality. Many sectoral laws orregulations <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>, as thus, legalise theformation and operation of cartels, which is aga<strong>in</strong>st the letters and spirits ofthe <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004. This law prohibits this type of anticompetitivehorizontal agreement, under its Article 8, which is expla<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> greater details<strong>in</strong> Article 16 of the Decree 116/2005. It is supposed to have supersed<strong>in</strong>g powerover competition issues. It is, therefore, difficult to see how this conflict isgo<strong>in</strong>g to be resolved.www.avenuev<strong>in</strong>e.comwww.acccgov.auAt least, similarly as the case of market shar<strong>in</strong>g agreements, the competitionauthority should make sure that this is not a ‘sham’ to cover an anticompetitive<strong>in</strong>tent. Inquiries could be made <strong>in</strong>to the actual market demand, <strong>in</strong> correlationto <strong>in</strong>dividual firms’ capacity and quotas enforced on them by the association.Further, output coord<strong>in</strong>ation does not mean shared distribution channels,22 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Box 2: Syndicate System <strong>in</strong> Surface TransportationMajority of transport entrepreneurs <strong>in</strong> Nepal have formed local syndicates,which allow none other than syndicate members to ply their vehicles onthe designated long routes. They have not only prevented otherentrepreneurs from enter<strong>in</strong>g the transport bus<strong>in</strong>ess, but were also <strong>in</strong>volved<strong>in</strong> vandalis<strong>in</strong>g buses which trespass on the demarcation of differentsyndicates.Syndicate operators claimed that they did not allow non-members/buses toply on ‘their’ highway, and if they did ply, they would be f<strong>in</strong>ed heavily.Companies outside the syndicate system felt that it created problem fortheir operations. They blamed the Government for be<strong>in</strong>g a mute spectatorof the system and held it responsible for perpetuat<strong>in</strong>g near monopoly,thereby reward<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>efficiency and carelessness.The Nepalese Government has adopted a liberalised and free economyabout a decade ago. Even though <strong>in</strong> its Transportation Act, the Governmentstill recognises the role of bus syndicates, there is no question of allow<strong>in</strong>gfor artificial ma<strong>in</strong>tenance of monopoly. Enforcement, however, rema<strong>in</strong>sweak, and the unstable political situation recently does not help much, ifnot worsen<strong>in</strong>g the situation.Nepal is <strong>in</strong> the process of adopt<strong>in</strong>g a competition law, <strong>in</strong> view of its accessioncommitments to the World Trade Organisation (WTO). However, eventhis process has been greatly delayed.RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESSource: Anticompetitive Practices <strong>in</strong> Nepal, Adhikari and Regmi, CUTS and SAWTEE,2001.identical charg<strong>in</strong>g prices or allocation of markets or customers. Any suchadditional ‘coord<strong>in</strong>ation’ may po<strong>in</strong>t to the existence of a cartel.4.4.4. Bid Rigg<strong>in</strong>g (or Collusive Tender<strong>in</strong>g)Another type of cartel behaviour is bid rigg<strong>in</strong>g. It isprohibited by Article 8 of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2006of <strong>Vietnam</strong> regardless of the market share of thecollud<strong>in</strong>g bidders. 33Bid rigg<strong>in</strong>g usually <strong>in</strong>volves competitorscollaborat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> some way to restrict competition <strong>in</strong>response to a tender, regardless of whether the tenderis issued by a public authority or a private entity. Itis universally viewed as one of the worst ‘hard-core’cartel-type offences alongside price-fix<strong>in</strong>g, output restriction and marketallocation, and is often a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of these practices. 34www.images.com<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 23


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESBox 3: Bloc Calendar – Cartel or anEfficiency-Enhanc<strong>in</strong>g AgreementUntil 2006, an association of 48 publish<strong>in</strong>g houses <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> werecoord<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g the output of bloc calendars for a decade, when they fell apart.Bloc calendars are the every day tear-off calendar, and produced and soldaround the time of a new year.In 2005, the association had agreed to produce a total amount of 13.5 millionbloc calendars to cater to the demand for the 2006 New Year of the wholecountry. These calendars were then produced and kept <strong>in</strong> stock with the<strong>Vietnam</strong> Book General Corporation, ready for distribution. Towards theend of 2005, however, the National University Publish<strong>in</strong>g House of Ho ChiM<strong>in</strong>h City (NUPH-HCM) suddenly withdrew their participation from theassociation and at the same time, announced that they would produce andmarket, all by themselves, a total amount of 2 million bloc calendars.The association and its other members were very agitated with this suddenmove. S<strong>in</strong>ce the NUPH-HCM was supposed to produce only 200,000calendars, the amount of calendars they then produced would overwhelmthe market. The association, therefore, lodged a compla<strong>in</strong>t with the GeneralDepartment of Publication (M<strong>in</strong>istry of Culture and Information). However,due to the <strong>in</strong>troduction of the <strong>Law</strong> on Publication 2004 and a document No.1187 on open<strong>in</strong>g up the publish<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess, the General Department couldneither f<strong>in</strong>d any fault with the decision of the NUPH-HCM, nor forced themto rejo<strong>in</strong> the association.While the old association accused the NUPH-HCM of not honour<strong>in</strong>g theircommitment, which caused supply to exceed demand, creat<strong>in</strong>g loss for all,the latter argued that they were only follow<strong>in</strong>g the spirit of liberalis<strong>in</strong>g thepublish<strong>in</strong>g sector. On the other hand, the NUPH-HCM accused theassociation of output restrict<strong>in</strong>g, and fix<strong>in</strong>g prices at a level higher thanshould be, caus<strong>in</strong>g loss to the consumers.Bid rigg<strong>in</strong>g, as all other cartel-type behaviours, can be difficult to detect andprosecute. However, as most competition laws broadly prohibit anticompetitiveagreements and concerted practices between competitors,there need be no legally b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g or formal agreement orany punishment or other enforcement mechanismsenvisaged for a bid rigg<strong>in</strong>g offence to be established. As <strong>in</strong>the case of other cartel types, circumstantial, rather thandirect evidence is often enough to <strong>in</strong>fer violations. 35Authorities are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly recognis<strong>in</strong>g the market conditions that make bidrigg<strong>in</strong>g more likely to occur. These <strong>in</strong>clude, for <strong>in</strong>stance: (i) the presence of afew sellers or of a small lead<strong>in</strong>g group of sellers that control most of the market;(ii) lack of ready substitution with other products; and (iii) standardised24 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>www.wisop<strong>in</strong>ion.com


www.cwa4322.orgproducts. This is also quite similar to the case of other cartel types. Whilerecent research shows that the build<strong>in</strong>g and civil eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g sector is at mostrisk of cartel activity, bid rigg<strong>in</strong>g cases have also been found <strong>in</strong> numerousother <strong>in</strong>dustries.4.4.5. Boycott or Jo<strong>in</strong>t Refusal to DealAn illegal boycott or jo<strong>in</strong>t refusal to deal is ajo<strong>in</strong>t action by competitors that has the purposeof us<strong>in</strong>g the comb<strong>in</strong>ed market power of thosecompetitors to force a supplier, a competitor ora customer to agree to an action that harmscompetition, which would not be agreed to,absent the jo<strong>in</strong>t action. For example, bythreaten<strong>in</strong>g to stop buy<strong>in</strong>g from a supplier, twovery large retail<strong>in</strong>g customers might be able toforce a supplier to agree not to sell one or moreof its products to otherretailers. If the supplier agreed, other retailstores would be los<strong>in</strong>g sales if no other bus<strong>in</strong>esswas available to supply the product to them.Further, the public would probably be hurt bothby the <strong>in</strong>convenience of f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g the product onlyat two stores. The use of this k<strong>in</strong>d of threat isusually designed either to put the other retailersout of bus<strong>in</strong>ess or to limit competition <strong>in</strong> the salesof the item to two stores to make it easier to raise theprice to the public.library.th<strong>in</strong>kquest.orgRESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESThe <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> prohibits such practices and hold themillegal irrespective of the comb<strong>in</strong>ed market share of the parties to the agreement,Box 4: A Case of Bid Rigg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>Bid rigg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> was discovered <strong>in</strong> many projects funded by theState budget. For <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong> Van Lam – Son Hai II road constructionproject, there were four companies participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the bidd<strong>in</strong>g for thisproject and ‘Company 98’ was awarded the contract. It was later discoveredthat all four participants belonged to the same bus<strong>in</strong>ess group whichCompany 98 controlled. Company 98 had arranged for three shellcompanies to submit <strong>in</strong>s<strong>in</strong>cere bids at <strong>in</strong>flated prices <strong>in</strong> order to create theillusion of a competitive process. Hav<strong>in</strong>g made these arrangements <strong>in</strong>advance, Company 98 was ensured, and <strong>in</strong>deed, awarded the contract at aprice with<strong>in</strong> ten millionths of a percent of the published governmentestimates (141 VND difference on a 1.56bn VND contract).Source: Tender<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Construction: Real <strong>Competition</strong> or not? - N<strong>in</strong>h Thuan Newspaper,December 17, 2002, as cited <strong>in</strong> CUTS (2006), Fairplay Please! p.118.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 25


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESBox 5: Complementary Bidd<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Pr<strong>in</strong>tersFour major pr<strong>in</strong>ters used to supply manifold bus<strong>in</strong>ess forms used forcomputer pr<strong>in</strong>tout paper, snap-set forms, and similar products. Historically,the government tendered orig<strong>in</strong>al orders but placed repeat orders with thefirm that had supplied the first order. After conclud<strong>in</strong>g that it could improveprices by tender<strong>in</strong>g all orders, the government began to do so from a list ofqualified pr<strong>in</strong>ters, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g four major firms. The resultant price decl<strong>in</strong>ebecame a concern to the major companies and their sales managers.The sales managers of the four companies met and agreed on a bidd<strong>in</strong>gstrategy. The price book of the market leader, available to all, was used todeterm<strong>in</strong>e benchmark prices for each product for all the companies. It wasagreed that when a tender was called, the previous supplier of the particularform would bid at or below the benchmark price, whereas all others wouldbid higher. After a while, the companies concluded that this method wastoo difficult and agreed that the former supplier would simply tell thecompetitors how much it was bidd<strong>in</strong>g and others would bid higher or not atall.Dur<strong>in</strong>g the conspiracy, about 300 separate tenders were called by thegovernment, and bidd<strong>in</strong>g patterns were consistent with the agreements.The arrangement started to break down after the entry of new competitor,which began w<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g bids. The new firm was approached to jo<strong>in</strong> the exist<strong>in</strong>gagreement. The new competitors, <strong>in</strong>stead, compla<strong>in</strong>ed to the authoritiesand provided <strong>in</strong>itial <strong>in</strong>formation that led to the start of the <strong>in</strong>vestigation.Source: Khemani, R. Shyam, A Framework for the Design Implementation of <strong>Competition</strong><strong>Law</strong> and Policy, World Bank and OECD, as cited <strong>in</strong> CUTS (2001), <strong>Competition</strong> Policy and<strong>Law</strong> Made Easy, p.10under its Article 8(6) and 8(7), which are further expla<strong>in</strong>ed by Article 19-20 ofthe Decree 116/2005.4.4.6. Other Horizontal Agreements between CompetitorsMany non-cartel horizontal agreements may be efficiency-enhanc<strong>in</strong>g bypromot<strong>in</strong>g research and development, create new or improved products ormethods of distribution or improve <strong>in</strong>formation flow. Many, on the other hand,may elim<strong>in</strong>ate competition, restrict output and raise prices.One example of such agreements is the case of standard-sett<strong>in</strong>g organisations.Efficiency justifications happen when, for <strong>in</strong>stance, some trade association ortest<strong>in</strong>g company says this k<strong>in</strong>d of electrical socket will safely fit <strong>in</strong> this k<strong>in</strong>d ofsocket, or this quality, grade, or whatever is safe to eat or safe to use <strong>in</strong>construction. These standards usually do not forbid the use of alternatives(unless they are put <strong>in</strong>to a build<strong>in</strong>g code or health code) but buyers are generallyafraid to use uncertified products so the effect is similar to a refusal to deal.26 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Box 6: India’s Pharma Retail CartelIn India, though there are 20,000 pharma manufacturers, there are nearly800,000 retailers. These retailers are said to dictate to the pharma companieswhat number of stockists a company should appo<strong>in</strong>t; how many brands orits comb<strong>in</strong>ations should be available <strong>in</strong> the market; what should be the freesamples policy and so on. Liberal marg<strong>in</strong>s are demanded and offered bythe pharma companies on generic drugs, go<strong>in</strong>g up to 2000 percent.In 1984, the Retail and Dispens<strong>in</strong>g Chemists Association, Bombay, wasbrought before the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Commission(MRTPC) after it directed all wholesalers and retailers to boycott acompany’s product till the Association’s demands were met by the company.The MRTPC observed that the impact of the chemists’ boycott could by nostretch of imag<strong>in</strong>ation be considered negligible. The boycott representedan attempt to deny the consumers certa<strong>in</strong> products to which they areaccustomed and, therefore, the hardship to such consumers was patent.The MRTPC then passed a ‘cease and desist’ order.Even before that, <strong>in</strong> 1982, the All India Organisation of Chemists andDruggists (AIOCD) had to face a similar fate. The AICOD was hauled upbefore the Commission <strong>in</strong> 1983 when it issued a circular to variouspharmaceutical companies threaten<strong>in</strong>g that if they dealt with the Statecooperative organisations and appo<strong>in</strong>ted them as stockists grant<strong>in</strong>g themsale rights, it would expose the companies to a boycott by its members.The case was decided <strong>in</strong> 1993 and the Commission struck it down as arestrictive trade practice of ‘refusal to deal’.RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESSource: Mehta, Pradeep S (2005), <strong>Competition</strong> Breaks Cartels, The H<strong>in</strong>du Bus<strong>in</strong>ess L<strong>in</strong>eon January 12, 2005, available at And the standard sett<strong>in</strong>g process can be abused to keep out competitors orkeep up prices which can be a violation of competition law.In another <strong>in</strong>stance, plumbers were able to discourage the build<strong>in</strong>g safetyassociation from approv<strong>in</strong>g the use of plastic sewage pipes because the plumberscould charge more for weld<strong>in</strong>g metal sewage pipes than they could for glu<strong>in</strong>gplastic ones. Similarly, doctors groups have been sued on a number of occasionsfor refus<strong>in</strong>g to allow their members to cooperate with nurse midwives or nurseanaesthetists, which generally makes it unlawful for those nurses to practicetheir specialties by themselves.The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, as mentioned above, adopts a rule of reasonapproach towards all such agreements. However, it fails to give the competitionauthority the pro-active power to exam<strong>in</strong>e the pro-competitive effects of suchpractice, leav<strong>in</strong>g them wait<strong>in</strong>g for the parties to the case to file an applicationfor exemption. A typical <strong>in</strong>vestigation over such practices, accord<strong>in</strong>g to the<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 27


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICES<strong>Law</strong>, shall <strong>in</strong>clude def<strong>in</strong>ition of relevant market for the case, verification of theparties’ market share <strong>in</strong> the relevant market already def<strong>in</strong>ed, and collectionand analysis of evidence on the violative acts. 36 This method, by itself, is ratherrigid, despite be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>comprehensive, and might prove <strong>in</strong>effective <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong>cases. Five other questions, which should be analysed to complement the<strong>in</strong>vestigative process, <strong>in</strong>clude: 37l whether the restra<strong>in</strong>t is <strong>in</strong>herently likely to restrict output and raise prices?l whether the restra<strong>in</strong>t is naked or obviously related to some pro-competitive<strong>in</strong>tegration of economic resources?l whether the restra<strong>in</strong>t will restrict outputs and raise prices, or otherwisecreate or facilitate the exercise of market power?l whether the restra<strong>in</strong>t is necessary to achieve the asserted pro-competitivegoals?l whether the restra<strong>in</strong>t’s pro-competitive benefits outweigh its anticompetitiverisks?4.5 Vertical Agreements <strong>in</strong> the Distribution/Sale of ProductsVertical anticompetitive agreementsVertical anticompetitiveagreements, which comeunder competitivescrut<strong>in</strong>y, are usuallycontractualarrangements betweensuppliers(manufacturers) anddistributors (retailers),which extend beyondsimple arms-lengthpric<strong>in</strong>g.<strong>in</strong>volve bus<strong>in</strong>esses operat<strong>in</strong>g at successivestages of a production process. Simply put,<strong>in</strong> a vertical arrangement, for examplebilateral, one party is the supplier of <strong>in</strong>putsto the other party’s bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity.Vertical agreements are, generallyspeak<strong>in</strong>g, treated less severely thanhorizontal ones, often under the rule ofreason by competition authorities.However, to be sure, certa<strong>in</strong> verticalagreements, which have adverse impact oncompetition <strong>in</strong> the market, have beenuniformly condemned, such as that of tiedsale, exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>g or resale pricema<strong>in</strong>tenance.Vertical anticompetitive agreements, which come under competitive scrut<strong>in</strong>y,are usually contractual arrangements between suppliers (manufacturers) anddistributors (retailers), which extend beyond simple arms-length pric<strong>in</strong>g. Theyare usually motivated by the desire for vertical control with<strong>in</strong> a pr<strong>in</strong>cipal-agentrelationship, where the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal (the manufacturer) imposes contractualobligations on its agent (the retailer) when delegat<strong>in</strong>g responsibility for sell<strong>in</strong>gits good. 38 This is <strong>in</strong> dist<strong>in</strong>ction from vertical restra<strong>in</strong>ts based upon dom<strong>in</strong>ance,which will be dealt with separately under a section on abuses of dom<strong>in</strong>ance.Such agreements may have a benign effect, e.g. by remov<strong>in</strong>g pric<strong>in</strong>g distortions,optimis<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestment levels and elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g avoidable transaction costs. Theymay also have an adverse effect not only by foreclos<strong>in</strong>g markets to new entrants(which is the standard criticism) but also by dampen<strong>in</strong>g competition betweenexist<strong>in</strong>g rivals through restrictions on <strong>in</strong>ter-brand and/or <strong>in</strong>tra-brandcompetition. 3928 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Similarly as horizontal restra<strong>in</strong>ts, it is often viewed that market power at oneor both levels is a necessary condition for vertical restra<strong>in</strong>ts to have a substantialadverse effect on competition. With market power present, a number of otherfactors, notably the effects on competition of the subject agreement, and any<strong>in</strong>dicator of efficiency, which might offset the agreement’s adverse effect oncompetition, should also be taken <strong>in</strong>to account while deal<strong>in</strong>g with these typesof vertical restra<strong>in</strong>ts. 40The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> does not deal with vertical restrictiveagreements <strong>in</strong> a direct manner. In fact, only three sections of Article 8 (whichlists out various competition-restrict<strong>in</strong>g agreements prohibited by the <strong>Law</strong>)could be <strong>in</strong>terpreted <strong>in</strong> this direction, which are Section 5-7. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, it isprohibited to have ‘agreements on impos<strong>in</strong>g on other enterprises conditionson sign<strong>in</strong>g of goods or services purchase or sale contracts or forc<strong>in</strong>g otherenterprises to accept obligations which have no direct connection with thesubject of such contracts’ (Article 8(5) of the <strong>Law</strong>), ‘agreements on prevent<strong>in</strong>g,restra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, disallow<strong>in</strong>g other enterprises to enter the market or developbus<strong>in</strong>ess’ (Article 8(6) of the <strong>Law</strong>), and ‘agreements on abolish<strong>in</strong>g from themarket enterprises other than the parties of the agreements’ (Article 8(7) of the<strong>Law</strong>). Interest<strong>in</strong>gly, these sections can apply for both the cases of horizontaland vertical relationship, as will be discussed later.4.5.1. Resale Price Ma<strong>in</strong>tenanceResale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenance is the practice whereby a manufacturer and itsdistributors agree that the latter will sellproducts of the former at certa<strong>in</strong> prices(resale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenance), at or above aprice floor (m<strong>in</strong>imum resale pricema<strong>in</strong>tenance) or at or below a price ceil<strong>in</strong>g(maximum resale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenance). 41RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESResale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenance sometimes mighthave benign effect, or help promotebus<strong>in</strong>ess efficiency, and would accord<strong>in</strong>glybe treated under the rule of reason. It ismost often an <strong>in</strong>strument for encourag<strong>in</strong>gservices of all types at the retail level. These services are th<strong>in</strong>gs like provid<strong>in</strong>gadvice to customers, keep<strong>in</strong>g enough staff so that cashier l<strong>in</strong>es are short, keep<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>ventory organised, even be<strong>in</strong>g enthusiastic, anyth<strong>in</strong>g that a retailer does apartfrom sett<strong>in</strong>g the price.However, <strong>in</strong> the early days of competition law, resale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenance wasconsidered to be noth<strong>in</strong>g more than an attempt to fix retail prices at a monopolylevel by a monopolist. The pr<strong>in</strong>ciple of per se illegality, therefore, was generallyapplied to deal with this practice, which is still applicable today <strong>in</strong> manycountries’ competition law. This is, however, more a unilateral conduct ratherthan a vertical concerted action or agreement.www.google.com<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 29


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESBox 7: South Africa Tribunal Puts Brakes onM<strong>in</strong>imum Resale Price Ma<strong>in</strong>tenanceThe <strong>Competition</strong> Tribunal of South Africa imposed a penalty of three millionrand (approx. US$419,000) on Federal Mogul Aftermarket South Africa(Pty) Ltd, for hav<strong>in</strong>g contravened the <strong>Competition</strong> Act. This is the largestpenalty levied by the <strong>Competition</strong> Tribunal. It follows an earlier f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g bythe Tribunal that Federal Mogul had engaged <strong>in</strong> resale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenanceby oblig<strong>in</strong>g distributors to sell Ferodo brake pads at a determ<strong>in</strong>ed priceand penalis<strong>in</strong>g those distributors who did not comply.Federal Mogul <strong>in</strong>itially argued that the Tribunal’s power to impose anadm<strong>in</strong>istrative penalty was unconstitutional. However, the Tribunal foundthat a respondent <strong>in</strong> prohibited practice cases was not <strong>in</strong> an analogousposition to a person accused <strong>in</strong> crim<strong>in</strong>al proceed<strong>in</strong>gs, and that the Actprovided adequate procedural mechanisms. Hence, the constitutional attackfailed.Whilst the maximum penalty (i.e. 10 percent of annual turnover) the Tribunalwas entitled to impose amounted to just over Rand 6mn (approx.US$838,000), the Tribunal found, after closer analysis of the factorsspecified <strong>in</strong> section 59(3) of the <strong>Competition</strong> Act, Rand 3mn (approx.US$419,000) was an appropriate penalty. As per the South African<strong>Competition</strong> Act, resale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenance is a species of price fix<strong>in</strong>g, andcannot be justified on the grounds that it may result <strong>in</strong> any technological,efficiency or pro-competitive ga<strong>in</strong>s.Source: Prabhala (2006), South Africa, <strong>Competition</strong> Regimes <strong>in</strong> the World – A Civil SocietyReport, CUTS, p.282.As a unilateral conduct, resale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenance is forbidden under Section 2of Article 13 (on Abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ance) of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of<strong>Vietnam</strong>. In the event that it serves to protect a dealer cartel’s members aga<strong>in</strong>stnew entry by more efficient firms, it is mentioned Article 8(6) of the <strong>Law</strong>, andis forbidden if the comb<strong>in</strong>ed market share of all members equals or exceeds 30percent of the relevant market. 42One of the most common areas of resale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenance is branded products.Manufacturers wish<strong>in</strong>g to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong> brand image often pressure retailersnot to discount their goods, fear<strong>in</strong>g that it may dim<strong>in</strong>ish the ‘exclusive image’of their goods.Another area where resale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenance rout<strong>in</strong>ely occurs is franchis<strong>in</strong>g.In this case, the franchisers may ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> a high degree of control overfranchisee bus<strong>in</strong>esses, for example dictat<strong>in</strong>g what products they can buy andsell, and how all the operations of the bus<strong>in</strong>ess are to be conducted, and <strong>in</strong>30 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


some cases, even dictat<strong>in</strong>g the m<strong>in</strong>imum prices for resale of goods, belowwhich their franchisees must not sell, depend<strong>in</strong>g on the content of the franchis<strong>in</strong>gagreement. In <strong>Vietnam</strong>, as well as <strong>in</strong> most other countries, franchis<strong>in</strong>g is anabsolutely lawful way of do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Therefore, the application of Article8(6) towards such agreements ought to be undertaken with caution.4.5.2. Exclusive Deal<strong>in</strong>gExclusive deal<strong>in</strong>g is a vertical agreement by which a retailer or wholesaler is‘tied’ to purchase from a supplier on the understand<strong>in</strong>g that no other distributorwill be appo<strong>in</strong>ted or receive supplies <strong>in</strong> a given area.It is frequently argued that exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>gagreements help a firm organise theirdistribution more efficiently. In such cases,where these agreements result <strong>in</strong> cost reductionor some other efficiency dividend, there mightnot be any competition problems associatedwith them, or only some m<strong>in</strong>imal ones. 43On the other hand, such agreements also tend to have adverse effect oncompetition, s<strong>in</strong>ce they may restrict the access of upstream rivals to distributors.Rivals may be foreclosed from the market altogether or, more commonly, forcedto use higher cost, or less effective, methods to br<strong>in</strong>g their products to market.In either case, competition can be reduced through either reduc<strong>in</strong>g the numberof manufacturers serv<strong>in</strong>g the market or by artificially rais<strong>in</strong>g the costs of somemanufacturers. 44Due to this dual nature, <strong>in</strong> some jurisdictions, the conduct is prohibited outright(per se), while it is subject to an effect test (whether it has substantially lessenedcompetition <strong>in</strong> a market) <strong>in</strong> others. In the US, for example, exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>gwas per se unlawful. However, a few years after mak<strong>in</strong>g this announcement,the US Supreme Court reversed itself <strong>in</strong> the GTE Sylvania case and declaredthat, <strong>in</strong> general, exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>g agreements are lawful. 45 There might belimitations to this rul<strong>in</strong>g if it could be shown that the exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>grequirements were, <strong>in</strong> a particular case, an effective method for monopolisation.Various forms of exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>g agreements are prohibited under Sections5 and 6 of Article 8 of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, though the term‘exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>g’ is not mentioned specifically there<strong>in</strong>.Article 8(5) of the <strong>Law</strong> prohibits those ‘agreement on impos<strong>in</strong>g on otherenterprises conditions on sign<strong>in</strong>g of goods or services purchase or sale contractsor forc<strong>in</strong>g other enterprises to accept obligations which have no directconnection with the subject of such contracts’ if the comb<strong>in</strong>ed market share ofthe parties to agreement equals or exceeds 30 percent of the relevant market(read <strong>in</strong> comb<strong>in</strong>ation with Art. 9(2) of the <strong>Law</strong>). The Decree 116/2005 furtherexpla<strong>in</strong>s, under its Article 18, such agreements <strong>in</strong> the light of either full-l<strong>in</strong>ewww.mooreslare.corante.comRESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICES<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 31


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESBox 8: Hungarian Book Publishers <strong>in</strong> TroubleThe Hungarian Association of Book Publishers and Book Retailers hasbeen found guilty of competition violations by the National <strong>Competition</strong>Council.In a decision on April 11, 2006, the Council decided that certa<strong>in</strong> rules ofthe Association were <strong>in</strong>tended to <strong>in</strong>troduce resale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenance, byrestrict<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dependent retailers from sell<strong>in</strong>g books below a certa<strong>in</strong> price.The Hungarian <strong>Competition</strong> Code conta<strong>in</strong>ed provisions prohibit<strong>in</strong>g ‘resaleat a loss’ – prices lower than the purchase price. This is illegal, if the selleris not an agent of the publisher.The code also prohibited the sale of big quantities on lower prices betweenMarch 01 and June 15 and between October 01 and December 31, 2005.Big quantities are books worth more than €192,300 (US$281,059).Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the Council, this was not only restrict<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>ter-brand but also<strong>in</strong>tra-brand competition.The Council has not imposed a f<strong>in</strong>e but has prohibited the use of theseprovisions and obliged the association to notify its members with<strong>in</strong> 15days.Source: http://www.globalcompetitionreview.com/news/news_item.cfm?item_id=3891forc<strong>in</strong>g or third-l<strong>in</strong>e forc<strong>in</strong>g, as mentioned above. However, <strong>in</strong>stead ofprohibit<strong>in</strong>g them per se, the <strong>Vietnam</strong> law and regulation <strong>in</strong>stead subject theseagreements to the ‘substantial lessen<strong>in</strong>g of competition test’.A comb<strong>in</strong>ed read<strong>in</strong>g of Article 8(6) and Article 9(2) of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> shows that exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>g agreements aimed at foreclos<strong>in</strong>gother enterprises to enter the market or develop bus<strong>in</strong>ess are prohibited <strong>in</strong><strong>Vietnam</strong> irrespective of the comb<strong>in</strong>ed market share of the parties to theagreement. In particular, Section 2a) of Article 19 of the Decree 116/2005,which expla<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> further details Article 8(6) of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>, mentionsthat the act of form<strong>in</strong>g an exclusive network with distributors and retailers tocreate difficulty for rivals is unlawful.4.5.3. Tied Sell<strong>in</strong>gTied sell<strong>in</strong>g is the practice of mak<strong>in</strong>g the sale of one good (the ty<strong>in</strong>g goods) tocustomers on the conditions of the purchase of a second good (the tied goods).Some k<strong>in</strong>ds of ty<strong>in</strong>g, especially by contract, have historically been regarded asanticompetitive as it is implied <strong>in</strong> this that one or more components of thepackage are sold <strong>in</strong>dividually by other bus<strong>in</strong>esses as their primary product,and thereby this bundl<strong>in</strong>g of goods would hurt their bus<strong>in</strong>ess. It is also impliedthat the company do<strong>in</strong>g this bundl<strong>in</strong>g has a significantly large market share sothat it would hurt the other companies who sell only s<strong>in</strong>gle components.32 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Ty<strong>in</strong>g has been defended as maximis<strong>in</strong>goverall welfare <strong>in</strong> a variety ofcircumstances. If the ma<strong>in</strong> product worksbetter with the tied product than withothers, the manufacturer may tie theproducts to avoid quality problems thatcould lead to product liability lawsuitsor loss of reputation. Ty<strong>in</strong>g may also beused with or <strong>in</strong> place of <strong>in</strong>tellectualproperty to help protect entry <strong>in</strong>to amarket, encourag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>novation.Ty<strong>in</strong>g is often used when the supplier makes one product that is critical tomany customers. By threaten<strong>in</strong>g to withhold that key product unless others arealso purchased, it is said; the supplier can <strong>in</strong>crease sales of less necessaryproducts.Box 9: Ceylon Oxygen Escapes Exclusive Deal<strong>in</strong>g ChargeCeylon Oxygen Ltd (COL) held approximately 80 percent market share <strong>in</strong>the production and distribution of oxygen gas and related products fromits <strong>in</strong>ception <strong>in</strong> 1936 until 1993 <strong>in</strong> Sri Lanka. Industrial Gases (Pvt) Ltd(IGL) commenced operations <strong>in</strong> this market <strong>in</strong> December 1993. In 1994,IGL objected to the behaviour of COL on the grounds of UTPs that weredetrimental to IGL.www.google.comRESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESIt was alleged that <strong>in</strong> the aftermath of IGL’s entry <strong>in</strong>to the market, COL hadresorted to predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g tactics, which were evidenced by a reduction<strong>in</strong> the deposit fee on oxygen cyl<strong>in</strong>ders from LKR 8,500 to LKR 3,000. Inaddition, there was a decrease <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong>tenance charges from LKR 75, toa range of LKR 55 to LKR 35 after IGL’s entry.Further, allegations were made of discrim<strong>in</strong>atory discounts and exclusivedeal<strong>in</strong>g, whereby COL had entered <strong>in</strong>to written agreements with its bulkpurchasers that made it compulsory for them to purchase their totalrequirements from COL for an agreed time period. It was also establishedthat substantial discounts were given on different types of gases and cyl<strong>in</strong>dercharges.On this matter, the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) identified three coursesof conduct that would constitute anticompetitive practices, namely predatorypric<strong>in</strong>g, discrim<strong>in</strong>atory rebates, and exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>g. However, the Courtof Appeal held that the FTC did not have the jurisdiction to <strong>in</strong>vestigatesuch practices under Section 11 of the FTC Act, and therefore, did notrecognise such conduct as ‘restrict<strong>in</strong>g, distort<strong>in</strong>g or prevent<strong>in</strong>g competition’with<strong>in</strong> the mean<strong>in</strong>g of Section 14.Source: CUTS (2002), Towards a New <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> Sri Lanka.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 33


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESBox 10: Promotional Strategy Foreclosed NewEntrant <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> Beer MarketTiger, He<strong>in</strong>eken and Biv<strong>in</strong>a (produced by the <strong>Vietnam</strong> Beer Jo<strong>in</strong>t-Venture)were alleged to have formed an alliance, us<strong>in</strong>g exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>g tactics toprevent Laser, the first <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese brand of bottled draught beer (producedby Tan Hiep Phat Corp.), from enter<strong>in</strong>g the marketMarketed <strong>in</strong> 2004, Laser beer, however, could not access retail shops,distribution agencies and bars, etc, due to the contracts these shops andagents had with the aforementioned beer producers, which <strong>in</strong>cluded anexclusive term prevent<strong>in</strong>g these sellers and distributors from sell<strong>in</strong>g,exhibit<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g, market<strong>in</strong>g… or even allow<strong>in</strong>g market<strong>in</strong>g staff ofany other beer brands to work on their bus<strong>in</strong>ess sites. As compensation,these shops and distributors would receive a ‘sponsor’ amount betweenVND50mn (US$3174) and some VND100mn (US$6349) per annum.To make matter worse, as a warn<strong>in</strong>g signal, just recently, a beer shop hasbeen brought to court by one of those big beer producers due to so-called‘violation of economic contract’. The decision of the Ho Chi M<strong>in</strong>h CityPeople’s Court was that the beer shop “Cay Dua” was not permitted toadvertise, sell or allow Laser market<strong>in</strong>g staff at their site until November2004; <strong>in</strong> accordance with the contract signed between the shop and the<strong>Vietnam</strong> Beer Jo<strong>in</strong>t-Venture s<strong>in</strong>ce November 2003.Though analysts op<strong>in</strong>ed that the terms of the contract were an abuse ofdom<strong>in</strong>ance by <strong>Vietnam</strong> Beer JV to compete unfairly and ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> itsdom<strong>in</strong>ant position by unjust practice, the contract was able to escape thescrut<strong>in</strong>y of the law, as <strong>Vietnam</strong> was yet to have a <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> at thetime, while the current Commercial <strong>Law</strong> and the State Ord<strong>in</strong>ance onEconomic Contracts did not cover these areas.Source: <strong>Vietnam</strong>Net, July 04, 2004 & May 18, 2004.In the recent <strong>in</strong>famous antitrust cases that Microsoft had <strong>in</strong> the US and EU, thesoftware giant was alleged to have tied together Microsoft W<strong>in</strong>dows, InternetExplorer, and W<strong>in</strong>dows Media Player. Microsoft’s view of it is that a webbrowser and a media player are simply part of an operat<strong>in</strong>g system (and are<strong>in</strong>cluded with all other personal computer operat<strong>in</strong>g systems). Just as thedef<strong>in</strong>ition of a car has changed to <strong>in</strong>clude th<strong>in</strong>gs that used to be separateproducts, such as speedometers and radios, the def<strong>in</strong>ition of an operat<strong>in</strong>g systemhas changed to <strong>in</strong>clude those formerly separate products. However, the deal<strong>in</strong>gUS court, for example, rejected Microsoft’s claim that Internet Explorer wassimply one facet of its operat<strong>in</strong>g system. At the same time, the court held thatthe tie between Microsoft W<strong>in</strong>dows and Internet Explorer should be analysedunder the rule of reason, and is not per se illegal. 4634 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Box 11: Ghana: Manufacturer vs ManufacturerAccra Brewery Ltd sued Gu<strong>in</strong>ness Ghana Ltd, seek<strong>in</strong>g an order of <strong>in</strong>terim<strong>in</strong>junction to restra<strong>in</strong> the latter from enter<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to or enforc<strong>in</strong>g an agreemententitled ‘Gu<strong>in</strong>ness means profit’ with outlet owners of alcoholic beverages.The pla<strong>in</strong>tiff manufactures products (Club Super Stout, Club Dark Beerand Castle Milk Stout) that compete with the products (Gu<strong>in</strong>ness ForeignExtra Stout) of Gu<strong>in</strong>ness. Accra Brewery’s arguments were that:l Gu<strong>in</strong>ness Ghana Ltd had entered <strong>in</strong>to a ‘money <strong>in</strong>duced’ agreementwith about 183 retailers of alcoholic beverages <strong>in</strong> 1999, which boundthese retailers to stock and advertise of only their products. Hence, theseretailers refused to stock the products of the Accra Brewery;l It was unlawful for Gu<strong>in</strong>ness to <strong>in</strong>duce their common customers to breaktheir contracts with Accra Brewery;l The conduct of Gu<strong>in</strong>ness was prevent<strong>in</strong>g the Ghanaian public fromexercis<strong>in</strong>g their freedom to choose any alcoholic or non-alcoholicbeverages <strong>in</strong> dr<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g bars, or other authorised places where both thecompanies’ products were sold;l Gu<strong>in</strong>ness’s act of <strong>in</strong>ducement contravened the tenets of social andeconomic liberty and prosperity of the <strong>in</strong>dividual to trade with whomhe pleases and the prosperity of the nation by the expansion of the totalvolume of trade; andl Accra Brewery had lost substantial <strong>in</strong>come as a consequence of theactivity of Gu<strong>in</strong>ness.RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESThe Judge ruled aga<strong>in</strong>st Accra Brewery, giv<strong>in</strong>g the judgment that:l There was no evidence of Gu<strong>in</strong>ness seek<strong>in</strong>g to create a monopoly;l There was no evidence that Gu<strong>in</strong>ness, by their own actions, was seek<strong>in</strong>gto prevent customers from buy<strong>in</strong>g similar products more cheaply fromelsewhere. This was s<strong>in</strong>ce the products had the same sale price that wasdeterm<strong>in</strong>ed by agreement among the producers; and customers werefree to choose which outlets they could buy from;l There was no evidence that Gu<strong>in</strong>ness’s market share had risen, as aconsequence of the agreement; andl There was no evidence that the public <strong>in</strong>terest was likely to suffer, as aresult of the agreement between Gu<strong>in</strong>ness and the selected retailers,s<strong>in</strong>ce consumers still had a choice.Source: Aryeetey & Ahene (2006), Ghana, <strong>Competition</strong> Regimes <strong>in</strong> the World– A Civil Society Report, CUTS, p.242.The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> did not provide for the prohibition oftied sell<strong>in</strong>g specifically. It, however, prohibits ‘agreement on impos<strong>in</strong>g on otherenterprises conditions on sign<strong>in</strong>g of goods or services purchase or sale contractsor forc<strong>in</strong>g other enterprises to accept obligations which have no directconnection with the subject of such contracts’ 47 if the comb<strong>in</strong>ed market shareof the parties to agreement equals or exceeds 30 percent of the relevant market.The Decree 116/2005 expla<strong>in</strong>s a little further on this po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> Section 1a) of its<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 35


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESArticle 18. However, it only mentions the illegality of the act of forc<strong>in</strong>g saleagents to sell or supply goods or services, which are not directly related to thesubject of the sale contracts.4.6. Abuse of Dom<strong>in</strong>ant PositionThe term ‘abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ant position’refers to anticompetitive bus<strong>in</strong>esspractices <strong>in</strong> which a dom<strong>in</strong>ant firmmay engage <strong>in</strong> order to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> or<strong>in</strong>crease its position <strong>in</strong> the market.These bus<strong>in</strong>ess practices by the firm,not without controversy, may beconsidered as “abusive or improperexploitation” of monopolistic controlof a market, aimed at restrict<strong>in</strong>gcompetition.The term ‘abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ant position’The term ‘abuse ofhas been explicitly <strong>in</strong>corporated <strong>in</strong>dom<strong>in</strong>ant position’ referscompetition laws of various countriesto anticompetitivesuch as Canada, the EU and Germany.bus<strong>in</strong>ess practices <strong>in</strong>In the US, the counterpart provisionswhich a dom<strong>in</strong>ant firmwould be those deal<strong>in</strong>g with monopolymay engage <strong>in</strong> order toand attempts to monopolise orma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> or <strong>in</strong>crease itsmonopolisation of a market. Which ofposition <strong>in</strong> the market.the different types of bus<strong>in</strong>ess practicesare considered as be<strong>in</strong>g abusive will varyon a case-by-case basis and across countries? Generally, the bus<strong>in</strong>ess practiceswhich have been contested are the follow<strong>in</strong>g:l price discrim<strong>in</strong>ation;l predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g;l price squeez<strong>in</strong>g by <strong>in</strong>tegrated firms;l refusal to deal/sell;l tied sell<strong>in</strong>g or product bundl<strong>in</strong>g; andl pre-emption of facilities.www.oxera.comQuite a few of these practices have already been discussed <strong>in</strong> the earlier sectionson vertical restrictive agreements, such as tied sell<strong>in</strong>g or product bundl<strong>in</strong>g andpre-emption of facilities (of which distribution/retail<strong>in</strong>g outlet is one), andhorizontal restrictive agreements as well,such as boycott and jo<strong>in</strong>t refusal to deal.This section, however, focuses more on the‘unilateral-conduct’ aspect of thesepractices.Besides, as also already mentioned <strong>in</strong>preced<strong>in</strong>g sections, the anticompetitive36 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


effects of various restrictive agreements are usually treated more harshly whenthere is a certa<strong>in</strong> degree of market power among the collud<strong>in</strong>g firms. Similarly,<strong>in</strong> this section, the subject practices, before be<strong>in</strong>g exam<strong>in</strong>ed about their harms/restra<strong>in</strong>ts on competition, have to go through the fist filter, which is to establishwhether the alleged firms possess market dom<strong>in</strong>ance or monopoly.Abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ance or monopoly position, as might have been mentionedbefore, is prohibited by the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> <strong>in</strong> its Article11-12, which provide a long list (though not necessarily exhaustive) of variouspractices by dom<strong>in</strong>ant firms, which would be deemed as violations of the law.The important po<strong>in</strong>t is that this group of prohibitions does not have an exemptionsection as <strong>in</strong> the case of anticompetitive agreements. Presumably, s<strong>in</strong>ce thedom<strong>in</strong>ant firms or group of firms or the monopolists, as def<strong>in</strong>ed by the <strong>Law</strong>,possess at least 30 percent of the relevant market, they have passed the ‘safeharbour’ threshold provided by the <strong>Law</strong>, and thus might be able to restra<strong>in</strong>competition.Box 12: Tie-up Sales of Gas Stoves with Supply of Gas ConnectionLike <strong>in</strong> any other command and control economies, some goods and serviceswere always <strong>in</strong> short supply, which led to political patronage andexploitation. Bus<strong>in</strong>esses exploited the situation through restrictive practiceslike tie-up sales. One such case, which came before the MRTPC of India <strong>in</strong>1984, was that of Shyam Gas Company. Shyam Gas Company, the soledistributor to Bharat Petroleum Corporation Ltd, for cook<strong>in</strong>g gas cyl<strong>in</strong>dersat Hathras (Uttar Pradesh), was allegedly engag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>grestrictive practices:l giv<strong>in</strong>g gas connections to the customer only when he purchased a gasstove or a hot plate from the company or its sister enterprise, ShyamJyoti Enterprises; andl charg<strong>in</strong>g customers for the supply of fitt<strong>in</strong>gs and appliances at twicethe market price.RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESThe MRTPC held that the company was <strong>in</strong>dulg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> an RTP that wasprejudicial to public <strong>in</strong>terest. When charged, Shyam Gas Co. agreed tostop the RTP, and the MRTPC directed the company to abide by theundertak<strong>in</strong>g.The company was also asked to display, on its notice board, that theconsumers were free to purchase the gas stoves and hot plates from anywherethey liked, and that the release of the gas connection would not be deniedor delayed if the stove or hot plate was not purchased from the company orits sister company. This order formed the basis of ask<strong>in</strong>g all LiquefiedPetroleum Gas (LPG) dealers to put up a similar notice <strong>in</strong> their premises.Source: Monopolies Trade Regulation & <strong>Consumer</strong> Protection, D P S Verma, 1985.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 37


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESBox 13: Tied Sale Practices <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> MarketsIn 2002, when the demand on the motorcycle labelled “Wave @” <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>was high, tied sell<strong>in</strong>g occurred <strong>in</strong> many shops <strong>in</strong> such way that the motorcyclewas sold tied with a helmet. In many cases, especially under the centrallyplanned economic mechanism, when the supply usually fell short of thedemand, tied sell<strong>in</strong>g practice was very popular.In mid-March 2004, the Informatics and Telecom Company <strong>in</strong> Ho Chi M<strong>in</strong>hCity (NetSoft) forced all of its agents <strong>in</strong> HCM City to sign contracts underthe conditions that each Internet agent must register for sell<strong>in</strong>g pre-paidInternet cards <strong>in</strong> addition to other services that they wish to register; and therevenue for sell<strong>in</strong>g such cards must reach at least VND400000 per month.Source: 1. http://vnexpress.net/<strong>Vietnam</strong>/K<strong>in</strong>h-doanh/2002/02/3B9B9479/2. Tr<strong>in</strong>h Thi Thanh Thuy et al, (2004), Scientific Background for Determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the Degree ofCompetitive Restrictive Agreements and Exemption Criteria <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>,Conference Report, MOT, Research Project 2003-78-009.Box 14: Local Bus<strong>in</strong>essman Squares up to SasolSouth Africa’s competition watchdog has recently handed a local bus<strong>in</strong>essa big victory over the <strong>in</strong>ternational oil company Sasol.On April 01, 2005, the <strong>Competition</strong> Tribunal found Sasol – a JohannesburgbasedMult<strong>in</strong>ational Corporation (MNC), which converts coal <strong>in</strong>to liquidfuel, such as gasol<strong>in</strong>e, diesel and heat<strong>in</strong>g oils – guilty of unlawful pricediscrim<strong>in</strong>ation, follow<strong>in</strong>g a compla<strong>in</strong>t by small bus<strong>in</strong>ess Nationwide Poles.Nationwide had orig<strong>in</strong>ally compla<strong>in</strong>ed to the <strong>Competition</strong> Commission.Follow<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>vestigation, the Commission concluded that there was noevidence of illegal price discrim<strong>in</strong>ation. Nationwide then compla<strong>in</strong>ed tothe Tribunal.Nationwide Poles buys creosote, a wood-treatment chemical, from Sasol.It had compla<strong>in</strong>ed that Sasol discrim<strong>in</strong>ated aga<strong>in</strong>st small bus<strong>in</strong>esses, alleg<strong>in</strong>gthat it was entitled to the full discount offered to Sasol’s bigger customers,such as its rival Woodl<strong>in</strong>e.Sasol claimed that it was not a dom<strong>in</strong>ant group and that creosote substituteswere freely available. The Tribunal disagreed, rul<strong>in</strong>g that Sasol had brokenantitrust law.Source: http://www.globalcompetitionreview.com/news/news_item.cfm?item_id=251338 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Article 117 of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> provides for a widerange of remedies, which would be applied <strong>in</strong> the case of f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g of abuse ofdom<strong>in</strong>ant positions, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g monetary f<strong>in</strong>es, public corrections, restructur<strong>in</strong>gof enterprises hav<strong>in</strong>g abused its dom<strong>in</strong>ant position <strong>in</strong> the market, revocation ofthe bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration certificates, and deprivation of licenses and practic<strong>in</strong>gcertificates, etc. Further stipulations <strong>in</strong> this area are made <strong>in</strong> the Decree No.120/2005/ND-CP issued by the Government of <strong>Vietnam</strong> on handl<strong>in</strong>gcompetition violations.Box 15: Promotion or Predatory Pric<strong>in</strong>g:Does Viettel Violate the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>?Viettel, a newcomer <strong>in</strong> the market for mobile phone services <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>,recently launched a huge promotional programme <strong>in</strong> September 2005, onenever undertaken <strong>in</strong> the country before. To celebrate its one-year operation,the army-run mobile service provider offered unlimited free first calls with<strong>in</strong>the network every day. Viettel has also offered free connection services fornew post-paid subscribers and doubled the account value for new pre-paidsubscribers. Viettel also cut mobile phone subscription fees by VND10,000to VND59,000 per month start<strong>in</strong>g October 01, 2005. The corporationmanagement board even announced that it would also keep the subscriptionfees 10 to 15 percent lower than other mobile phone networks.Many subscribers have warmly welcomed this move of Viettel. Others,however, rema<strong>in</strong>ed sceptical that the quality of services might not matchthe largeness of the promotions. Analys<strong>in</strong>g from the angle of the <strong>Competition</strong><strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, many also asked whether such a promotionconstituted an act of predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g – a violation under this law.RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESTran Anh Son, Deputy Director of the <strong>Competition</strong> Adm<strong>in</strong>istrationDepartment under the M<strong>in</strong>istry of Trade of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, op<strong>in</strong>ed that Viettel’soffer of free connection services for new post-paid subscribers was <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>ewith Section B, Article 181 of the <strong>Law</strong> on Commerce, and that thecompetition law does not prohibit such promotions. Answer<strong>in</strong>g questionswhether Viettel’s move might be an unfair competition practice to attractcompetitors’ clientele, or a predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g conduct, Son said that theprovision of the competition law on predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g only applied todom<strong>in</strong>ant enterprises with more than 30 percent market share, while Viettelcontrolled only 10 percent of the market at the time. He stressed that Viettel’spric<strong>in</strong>g behaviour was not predatory and did not violate the <strong>Competition</strong><strong>Law</strong>.Source: VietNamNet, September 24, 2005.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 39


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESBox 16: Predatory Practices <strong>in</strong> the Beer Sector <strong>in</strong> ZimbabweNesbitt Brewery (Pvt) Limited, a small brew<strong>in</strong>g company located atChiredzi, Zimbabwe, lodged a compla<strong>in</strong>t with the <strong>Competition</strong>Commission of Zimbabwe that National Breweries Limited was engaged<strong>in</strong> predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g, hav<strong>in</strong>g drastically reduced the price of clear beer <strong>in</strong>Chiredzi to unprofitable levels, with the <strong>in</strong>tention of driv<strong>in</strong>g Nesbitt Breweryout of the market.Investigations revealed that the clear beer <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> Zimbabwe was highlyconcentrated. Nesbitt Brewery was a new entrant <strong>in</strong>to the market,challeng<strong>in</strong>g the long-stand<strong>in</strong>g monopoly position of National Breweries,which held a market share of 90 percent. National Breweries has a nationaldistribution network, whilst Nesbitt Brewery only operates <strong>in</strong> Chiredzi.Investigations further revealed that the National Breweries had organiseda beer promotion <strong>in</strong> Chiredzi from May 1999 to April 2000, when theCommission started gather<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation on the case. The promotion<strong>in</strong>cluded free snacks and T-shirts, lucky draw tickets, free beers andsubstantial price reductions. The promotion was only held <strong>in</strong> Chiredzi,where Nesbitt Brewery is based and also sells the bulk of its beer. TheNational Breweries retail prices for its beer, <strong>in</strong> Chiredzi dur<strong>in</strong>g the promotionperiod, were below its normal landed costs <strong>in</strong> that town.The Commission conducted a full-scale <strong>in</strong>vestigation under section 28 ofthe <strong>Competition</strong> Act of 1996. The alleged practices were found to bepredatory with<strong>in</strong> the terms of Section 2 of the Act. Although NationalBreweries stopped their promotion activities as soon as they became awarethat they were be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestigated, the Commission made them sign anundertak<strong>in</strong>g that they would desist from future promotional activitiesprimarily aimed at driv<strong>in</strong>g Nesbitt Brewery out of the market.Source: UNCTAD Intergovernmental Group of Experts on <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> and Policy,Geneva, July 03-05, 2002.4.6.1. Price Discrim<strong>in</strong>ationPrice discrim<strong>in</strong>ation refers to the practice ofapply<strong>in</strong>g different conditions, normally differentprices, to equivalent transactions. A simpleexample is the practice of charg<strong>in</strong>g of differentprices to different customers, or categories ofcustomers, for the same product where thedifferences <strong>in</strong> prices do not reflect the quantity, quality or any othercharacteristics of the items supplied.Price discrim<strong>in</strong>ation is prohibited <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>,under its Article 13(4). Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>Law</strong>, such are the practices ofwww.images.com40 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Box 17: Viettel Mobile Faces Bankruptcy due to VNPT’s MonopolyThe fledg<strong>in</strong>g Viettel mobile phone service provider <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> compla<strong>in</strong>edto the Government of its potential bankruptcy caused by a deadlock overnetwork connection with the <strong>Vietnam</strong> Posts and TelecommunicationsGeneral Corporation (VNPT). The General Corporation was accused oflimit<strong>in</strong>g phone calls by Viettel customers to VNPT’s mobile and landl<strong>in</strong>esubscribers.Under the current <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese regulations, VNPT, as <strong>Vietnam</strong>’s largestmobile phone and landl<strong>in</strong>e service provider and the dom<strong>in</strong>ant market holder,must ensure there is communications connection between the corporationand other start-up companies. The two companies had even concluded adeal <strong>in</strong> December 2004 over connection issues. Notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g, whileViettel’s mobile phone subscription rocketed <strong>in</strong> the first six months of 2005,VNPT has only provided less than 50 percent of the connection demand,trigger<strong>in</strong>g a wave of compla<strong>in</strong>ts by Viettel customers about service quality.VNPT expla<strong>in</strong>ed that it was not VNPT’s <strong>in</strong>tention to cause trouble to Viettel.The problem was said to have been caused by VNPT’s circuit switchboardsus<strong>in</strong>g old technology and at present it would not be economically efficientto upgrade the system. Viettel said the explanation was irrational as VNPTonly needed to <strong>in</strong>vest US$2mn or 0.3 percent of its total annual <strong>in</strong>vestmentcapital to satisfy demand for Viettel, far less than the US$30mn Viettelreportedly paid VNPT for connection <strong>in</strong> 2004.RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESSource: CUTS 7Up2 Project, Advocacy and Capacity Build<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>Competition</strong> Policy and<strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> Asia, E-Newsletter Vol. V.“impos<strong>in</strong>g dissimilar commercial conditions <strong>in</strong> similar transactions <strong>in</strong> order tocreate <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> competition”. This is further def<strong>in</strong>ed under Article 29 ofthe Decree 116/2005.In countries with a long heritage of centrally plann<strong>in</strong>g like <strong>Vietnam</strong>, where thestate sector assumed, and still does, a great importance, such discrim<strong>in</strong>atorytreatment is quite prevalent. In cases where the competitive balanced is unjustlytitled because of such practices, the competition should try to have a say toprotect economic justice. Especially <strong>in</strong> the case of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, where ‘enterprisesproduc<strong>in</strong>g/supply<strong>in</strong>g products or public-utility services, enterprises operat<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> the State-monopolised sectors and doma<strong>in</strong>s’ are also subject to the scrut<strong>in</strong>yof the competition law. 484.6.2. Predatory Pric<strong>in</strong>gPredatory pric<strong>in</strong>g occurs when a dom<strong>in</strong>ant firm temporarily charges particularlylow prices <strong>in</strong> an attempt to elim<strong>in</strong>ate exist<strong>in</strong>g competitors, or create a barrierto entry <strong>in</strong>to the market for potential new competitors. The predator will <strong>in</strong>curtemporary losses dur<strong>in</strong>g its low pric<strong>in</strong>g policy with the <strong>in</strong>tention of rais<strong>in</strong>gprices <strong>in</strong> the future to recoup losses and ga<strong>in</strong> further profits. Such behaviour<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 41


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESmay offer consumers advantages <strong>in</strong> the short run butwill be disadvantageous if the seller is able toma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> the price at a monopoly level.Predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g necessarily <strong>in</strong>volves the ability toraise prices once rivals have been discipl<strong>in</strong>ed or haveexited the market. Consequently, a key consideration<strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g that low prices are <strong>in</strong> fact predatoryand may lead to a substantial lessen<strong>in</strong>g of competitionis whether the market is viewed by potentialcompetitors as hav<strong>in</strong>g high barriers to entry. Suchbarriers might <strong>in</strong>clude high f<strong>in</strong>ancial costs for entry,with difficult technology and little ability to sell off the assets if the new entryfails. Without such barriers, any post-predation price <strong>in</strong>crease by the dom<strong>in</strong>antfirm might attract entry so that the dom<strong>in</strong>ant firm would not be able to raiseprices and recoup the costs of predation. 49Box 18: IPRs over Weekly TV Guide AbusedThe ECJ, <strong>in</strong> its decision of 6 April 1995, confirmed that Radio TelefisEireann (RTE) and Independent Television Publications Limited (ITP),who were the only sources of basic <strong>in</strong>formation on programme schedul<strong>in</strong>g,which is <strong>in</strong>dispensable raw material for compil<strong>in</strong>g a weekly television guide,could not rely on national copyright provisions to refuse to provide that<strong>in</strong>formation to third parties. Such a refusal, the Court held, <strong>in</strong> this caseconstituted the exercise of an IPR beyond its specific subject matter and,thus, an abuse of a dom<strong>in</strong>ant position under Article 86 of the Treaty ofRome.www.images.comThe court argued that RTE and ITP held a dom<strong>in</strong>ant position, because theywere the only source <strong>in</strong> Ireland of the basic <strong>in</strong>formation necessary to produceweekly television programm<strong>in</strong>g guides and were thus <strong>in</strong> a position to reservefor themselves the secondary market for weekly television guides byexclud<strong>in</strong>g all competition from that market.The Court considered that, whilst refusal to grant a license <strong>in</strong> exercis<strong>in</strong>g anIPR is not of itself an abuse of a dom<strong>in</strong>ant position, it might be an abusewhere special circumstances exist. Such circumstances <strong>in</strong>cluded the lackof an actual or potential substitute for a weekly television guide, theexistence of a specific, constant and regular demand for such a guide, andthe fact that the refusal to grant a license to Magill to produce such a guideprevented the appearance of a new product on the market which RTE andITP did not offer.Source: Jo<strong>in</strong>ed Cases 241/91 P etc. RTE and ITP v Commission [1995] ECR I-743.42 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g is prohibited <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, underits Article 13(1). Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>Law</strong>, such are the practices of ‘sell<strong>in</strong>g goods,provid<strong>in</strong>g services at prices lower than the aggregate costs <strong>in</strong> order to elim<strong>in</strong>atecompetitors’. This is further def<strong>in</strong>ed under Article 23-26 and Article 31 of theDecree 116/2005, which details quite a lot of criteria for calculat<strong>in</strong>g costs <strong>in</strong>such cases. Broadly, such costs <strong>in</strong>clude manufacture costs, distribution costs,and managerial costs.The Decree also mentions some cases where sell<strong>in</strong>g below cost is not consideredas predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g, such as <strong>in</strong> the case of prices for perishables, off-seasonproducts/services, sale off, or prices regulated by the State. However, <strong>in</strong> suchcases, price cuts have to be expla<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the clearest form possible at the sell<strong>in</strong>gpo<strong>in</strong>ts.4.6.3. Refusal to Deal/SupplyAbsent a statute or other special circumstances, a bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> a free market hasan unlimited right to refuse to do bus<strong>in</strong>ess with any buyer for any reason or forno reason at all. This spirit is upheld by the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong><strong>in</strong> its Article 4, which says, “Enterprises enjoy freedom to competition with<strong>in</strong>the legal framework. The State protects the lawful right to bus<strong>in</strong>esscompetition”.However, <strong>in</strong> many a case, one will see that the competition statutes of manycountries prohibit such practice whereby a supplier refuses to supply goods toa dealer without reasonable justifications. In other more special <strong>in</strong>stances, itmight be the case that one dom<strong>in</strong>ant bus<strong>in</strong>ess which is <strong>in</strong> possession of ‘essentialfacilities’ <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dustry or a market is prohibited by the competition law torefuse/restrict access to those facilities by competitors, if this is seen as aneffort to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> its dom<strong>in</strong>ant position. 50RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESwww.images.com<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 43


RESTRICTIVE BUSINESS PRACTICESA supplier may refuse to supply for various reasons, for example to control theretail prices at which its products are sold or to protect its downstream markets.A situation may arise <strong>in</strong> which a supplier recommends resale prices to its dealersand refuses to supply those dealers who do not resell at these prices.The problem arises when one firm is active <strong>in</strong> both upstream and downstreamactivities (it is vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated) and refuses to grant other firms, who wishto provide either upstream or downstream services only, access to the “facility”.The refusal to supply may be anticompetitive if it prevents third party firmsfrom enter<strong>in</strong>g the market and consequently has the effect of lessen<strong>in</strong>gcompetition. A dom<strong>in</strong>ant firm, which controls access to an essential facility,may be abus<strong>in</strong>g its dom<strong>in</strong>ant position if it refuses access to the facility withoutreasonable justification or grants access only on discrim<strong>in</strong>atory terms suchthat its competitors <strong>in</strong> the related market are disadvantaged.Refusal to deal/supply is not explicitly mentioned as be<strong>in</strong>g prohibited <strong>in</strong> the<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, except <strong>in</strong> Article 13(6) and Article 8(6) aswell as other provisions (e.g. Article 14), which seem to prohibit some k<strong>in</strong>dsof discrim<strong>in</strong>ation aga<strong>in</strong>st exist<strong>in</strong>g or potential entrants as competitors or retailersof the products made by a firm. Article 20 of the Decree 116/2005, whenexpla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the concept of restrictive agreements aimed at elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g from themarket firms which are not parties to the agreement (prohibited irrespective ofthe comb<strong>in</strong>ed market share of the parties to the agreement under Article 8(7)of the <strong>Law</strong>), did mention someth<strong>in</strong>g related to a jo<strong>in</strong>t refusal to deal or jo<strong>in</strong>tpredatory pric<strong>in</strong>g tactics. However, noth<strong>in</strong>g was mentioned <strong>in</strong> either the <strong>Law</strong>or the Decree 116/2005 about such unilateral conduct, or an act of restrict<strong>in</strong>gaccess to essential facilities. It was not mentioned either under Article 31 ofthe Decree 116/2005 about erect<strong>in</strong>g barriers to entry to new competitors, which<strong>in</strong>cludes only exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>g and predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g tactics.Other sectoral regulations <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>, such as the Ord<strong>in</strong>ance No 43/2002 onPosts and Telecommunications and the Electricity <strong>Law</strong> 2004, however, domention the obligation on the part of <strong>in</strong>cumbent bus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> these sectors toprovide <strong>in</strong>terconnection to their network to competitors on fair terms. TheOrd<strong>in</strong>ance No 43/2002 on Posts and Telecommunications, for example,provides for such obligations to be placed on parties who are <strong>in</strong> a dom<strong>in</strong>antposition <strong>in</strong> respect of provision of <strong>in</strong>terconnect and who control “essentialfacilities” (though this key term is left undef<strong>in</strong>ed). These obligations providefor good faith negotiations and prohibit refusal to <strong>in</strong>terconnect.44 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


5. ENFORCEMENT OF THE COMPETITIONLAW AGAINST RBPsRBPs <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>, accord<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004, may be <strong>in</strong>vestigatedsuo moto by the <strong>Competition</strong> Adm<strong>in</strong>istration Department (CAD), as well asupon receipt of a compla<strong>in</strong>t. 51 Any organisation or <strong>in</strong>dividual believ<strong>in</strong>g theirrights and <strong>in</strong>terests have been <strong>in</strong>fr<strong>in</strong>ged by a violation of the <strong>Law</strong> (for <strong>in</strong>stance,a company that th<strong>in</strong>ks the practices of a competitor are <strong>in</strong> breach of the <strong>Law</strong>)has the right to lodge a compla<strong>in</strong>t with the CAD. (Article 58(1) of the <strong>Law</strong>)The time limit for commencement of <strong>in</strong>vestigation is two years from the dateon which the alleged breach of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> occurred.A compla<strong>in</strong>t file must <strong>in</strong>clude evidence of the competitive practice which iscompla<strong>in</strong>ed of. The CAD will return a compla<strong>in</strong>t file to the compla<strong>in</strong>ant if thelimitation period has expired, if the case is beyond the CAD’s <strong>in</strong>vestigativeauthority, or if the file is not complete (or supplemented with<strong>in</strong> the deadl<strong>in</strong>e).A compla<strong>in</strong>ant may appeal aga<strong>in</strong>st the return of a compla<strong>in</strong>t with<strong>in</strong> five daysof the return; and the M<strong>in</strong>ister of Trade must decide the appeal with<strong>in</strong> sevendays of the appeal. If a compla<strong>in</strong>t is accepted, an advance worth 100 milliondong (equivalent to more than US$6000) are payable with<strong>in</strong> 15 days <strong>in</strong> provisionfor costs of case handl<strong>in</strong>g by the CAD, <strong>in</strong> the case of compla<strong>in</strong>ts on competitionrestra<strong>in</strong>ts. (Article 62-63 of the <strong>Law</strong> and Article 47(1) & 53 of the Decree 116/2005). This fees will be refunded to a successful compla<strong>in</strong>ant, as costs will bepayable by the offender. The competition authority will bear the entire fees <strong>in</strong>cases where they acted suo moto but theThere are some issueswhich should be taken<strong>in</strong>to account by thecompetitionauthorities dur<strong>in</strong>g thelaw enforcementprocess for effectivecase handl<strong>in</strong>g.suspected enterprises are not foundguilty. (Article 63(3) of the <strong>Law</strong>) Uponpayment of fees, the CAD willcommence competition legalproceed<strong>in</strong>gs based on the compla<strong>in</strong>t.The follow<strong>in</strong>g diagram illustrates <strong>in</strong> briefhow competition proceed<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>take place. 52 Other than the hardprocedural aspects, there are some issueswhich should be taken <strong>in</strong>to account by the competition authorities dur<strong>in</strong>g thelaw enforcement process for effective case handl<strong>in</strong>g.5.1. Detection of ViolationsAt least three classes of people will provide competition authorities with<strong>in</strong>formation that sometimes leads to <strong>in</strong>vestigations and f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs of competitionlaw violations: confidential <strong>in</strong>formants (employees or persons or bus<strong>in</strong>esses<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 45


46 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>Art. 58.1, 59.1, 86.1Receive Compla<strong>in</strong>tArt. 86.8Initiate CaseArt. 22Receive merger dossierArt. 23.1Decide on Economic ConcentrationENFORCEMENT OF THE COMPETITION LAW AGAINST RBPsA rt. 76.7, 86,87Prelim<strong>in</strong>aryInvestigationArt. 88.1Decide to stop<strong>in</strong>vestigationArt. 88.2OfficialInvestigationà Art. 117Decision onViolation/SanctionArt. 107.2Appeal to TradeM<strong>in</strong>isterArt. 115.1Appeal to CourtsArt. 93.1Report to Com petitionCouncilA rt. 99.2, 101Decision tostopArt. 79.1Appo<strong>in</strong>tPanelArt. 98, 104Hear<strong>in</strong>gArt. 81.3Decision on Violationand SanctionArt. 107.1Appeal to full<strong>Competition</strong> CouncilArt. 19.1 When Danger ofdissolution or bankruptcy:Art.101.1(a)Proposal tostopArt. 112Decision on Appeal by full<strong>Competition</strong> CouncilArt. 32.1ReceiveexemptionapplicationArt. 25.1 Trade M<strong>in</strong>ister DecidesArt. 19.2 W hen the effect willexpand export or contribute todevelopment:Art. 25.2 Prime M<strong>in</strong>ister DecidesArt. 38Appeal underthe <strong>Law</strong> onCompla<strong>in</strong>tsandDenunciationsArt. 112.1Hold upArt. 115.1Appeal to CourtsArt. 112.2AmendArt. 112.3Remand


seek<strong>in</strong>g to take advantage of leniency provisions); victims of anticompetitivepractices (generally customers or suppliers who suspect that the reason thatthey cannot get a deal for price they expect is that the price/supply is be<strong>in</strong>gartificially raised by a cartel); and, employees of the competition authoritieswho monitor public actions of <strong>in</strong>dustries (for example, a competition<strong>in</strong>vestigator would not f<strong>in</strong>d it unusual for prices of different producers to beabout the same for identical products because the higher price seller wouldf<strong>in</strong>d no buyers; but the <strong>in</strong>vestigator would strongly suspect that a price cartelexists if the only five producers of identical products announced at the exactsame time a price <strong>in</strong>crease of the exact same amount).Now there are strong reasons that some people, perhaps most, who fall <strong>in</strong>tothese three categories might be unwill<strong>in</strong>g to file a public compla<strong>in</strong>t or pay theadvance, as provided for <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>. Consider,for example, an employee who overhears a conversation or sees a documentthat <strong>in</strong>dicates that his (or her) company is party to a price cartel. As a goodcitizen, he may be will<strong>in</strong>g to tell the competition authorities about his suspicions.But so long as they are only suspicions, he would not like the company toknow what he said. In fact, competition authorities normally would attempt tokeep both the person’s identity and the allegations confidential until more<strong>in</strong>formation was obta<strong>in</strong>ed. Indeed, they are likely to want the <strong>in</strong>formant toseek further evidence of the unlawful activity, which would be impossible ifthe company knew the employee was talk<strong>in</strong>g to the competition authorities.Moreover, the employee is unlikely to have the money to pay the 100-milliondongadvance or any desire to pay it.Much the same is true of a co-conspirator who is seek<strong>in</strong>g leniency. Such anenterprise may have enough money, but they may not be sure that there will beenough evidence to prove the conspiracy if the allegations are made publicbefore an <strong>in</strong>vestigation. If the cartel members have been careful <strong>in</strong> arrang<strong>in</strong>gmeet<strong>in</strong>gs and have no written agreements, and especially if there has beensome cheat<strong>in</strong>g by cartel members, the testimony of a s<strong>in</strong>gle competitor may be<strong>in</strong>sufficient to prove that the cartel existed. They might simply deny the meet<strong>in</strong>gsor agreement and po<strong>in</strong>t to the <strong>in</strong>stances of cheat<strong>in</strong>g (sell<strong>in</strong>g at less than theagreed upon price) as evidence that there never was an agreement on price.<strong>Competition</strong> authorities might, therefore, encourage the <strong>in</strong>formant to meet aga<strong>in</strong>with the other cartel members at a place where the authorities might videotapethe cartel members (as happened <strong>in</strong> the US <strong>in</strong> the lys<strong>in</strong>e cartel case).ENFORCEMENT OF THE COMPETITION LAW AGAINST RBPsCustomers might be will<strong>in</strong>g to suggest to the competition authorities that theirsuppliers seem to be engaged <strong>in</strong> a customer allocation cartel. The customermight suspect this if he tried to f<strong>in</strong>d a new supplier and the first two newsuppliers he tried said that they have committed all of their supplies to exist<strong>in</strong>gcustomers. The customer who has made this allegation might try to f<strong>in</strong>d out ifhis rivals also face the same problem, but it is not clear that his rivals have an<strong>in</strong>centive to tell him the truth and if word gets out that he has compla<strong>in</strong>ed to thecompetition authorities, the suppliers may make his supply problems more<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 47


ENFORCEMENT OF THE COMPETITION LAW AGAINST RBPsdifficult. While it is likely that the customer will have to testify at some time,he could assist the competition authorities if he could try to gather additionalevidence of an allocation cartel before the cartel member become aware of the<strong>in</strong>vestigation.The tim<strong>in</strong>g of notification to suspected violators is also crucial to be<strong>in</strong>g able togather additional <strong>in</strong>formation about a suspected violation. In the example offirms rais<strong>in</strong>g prices at the exact same time, it is possible that some externalevent or series of events caused the companies to announce their price <strong>in</strong>creaseat the same time. For example, if an association of bus<strong>in</strong>ess that purchasedtheir products was about to meet and the competitors all learned that theirsuppliers were go<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>crease their prices; it is conceivable that all the firms<strong>in</strong>dividually decided that it would be prudent to announce the price <strong>in</strong>creasebefore the meet<strong>in</strong>g. A non-public <strong>in</strong>vestigation is more likely to be able todeterm<strong>in</strong>e the facts and avoid the possibilities of wrongly accus<strong>in</strong>g a group of<strong>in</strong>nocent companies of violat<strong>in</strong>g the law or giv<strong>in</strong>g violators warn<strong>in</strong>g of the<strong>in</strong>vestigation and allow<strong>in</strong>g them to make up an untrue story to disprove theviolation.The idea that an <strong>in</strong>vestigator should or the competition authority should get anadvance on their fee for handl<strong>in</strong>g a case before conduct<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>vestigation, as<strong>in</strong> the case of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, therefore, is not recommended. Besides, it might notbe a good idea to announce publicly that a competition <strong>in</strong>vestigation is tak<strong>in</strong>gplace before the <strong>in</strong>vestigation is concluded. An announcement should be madeonly when the <strong>in</strong>vestigation is concluded. The reason that all <strong>in</strong>vestigationsare non-public is both to make it easier for the staff to conduct the <strong>in</strong>vestigationand because it can unnecessarily damage a company if it is known to be under<strong>in</strong>vestigation and then later it turns out that the company has committed noviolation.5.2. Obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Proof of ViolationsThe k<strong>in</strong>d of proof needed will dependThe k<strong>in</strong>d of proof neededwill depend on the natureof the violation and theproof required <strong>in</strong> order toshow that thecompetition law hasbeen violated.on the nature of the violation and theproof required <strong>in</strong> order to show that thecompetition law has been violated.Market shares: These are a set of numberthat are required <strong>in</strong> prov<strong>in</strong>g certa<strong>in</strong>unlawful RBPs, abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ance,and unlawful mergers or jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures(as will be discussed <strong>in</strong> Section 6). Forexample, Article 8(1-5) of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 requires proof of marketshares; while Article 8(6-8) does not. Proof of dom<strong>in</strong>ance also requires ademonstration of market shares.In order to determ<strong>in</strong>e market shares, it is necessary to def<strong>in</strong>e the market anddeterm<strong>in</strong>e the share of the enterprise or enterprises that are be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestigated.48 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


As discussed earlier, this requires both a determ<strong>in</strong>ation of the product marketand the geographic market. In general, competition authorities beg<strong>in</strong> with whattheir <strong>in</strong>vestigators know as <strong>in</strong>dividuals, what the authorities know from previous<strong>in</strong>vestigations, and what <strong>in</strong>formation is available from public sources.As a result, an <strong>in</strong>vestigation might be compared to creat<strong>in</strong>g a map ofundiscovered territory. In an <strong>in</strong>vestigation of manufacturers of a product, onemight start by <strong>in</strong>terview<strong>in</strong>g retail stores to determ<strong>in</strong>e what products areconsidered substitutes by consumers and what enterprises can sell the retailerthe supplies, whether the suppliers must have local production facilities orwhether the product is produced on a national or <strong>in</strong>ternational level. Such<strong>in</strong>terviews might be just a start to def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the product and geographic market.The list of manufacturers ga<strong>in</strong>ed from the retailers would provide a start thatmight be followed up with <strong>in</strong>terviews with distributors or wholesalers. Any ofthese <strong>in</strong>terviews might po<strong>in</strong>t to other manufacturers who could make theproducts or who might be plann<strong>in</strong>g to make the products. Little by little aconsistent picture of the <strong>in</strong>dustry is likely to emerge as the answers of bus<strong>in</strong>essesare cross checked. Ultimately, it will be necessary to ga<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation from themanufacturers themselves to determ<strong>in</strong>e the size of their sales <strong>in</strong> the relevantmarket and their capacity to manufacture additional products for that market.Most established competition authorities can quickly put together a prelim<strong>in</strong>arysketch of an <strong>in</strong>dustry from voluntary <strong>in</strong>terviews with market participants.Obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g such <strong>in</strong>formation voluntarily and quickly is possible only if thebus<strong>in</strong>esses have confidence that the competition authorities will keep bus<strong>in</strong>ess<strong>in</strong>formation secret. The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> requires that thecompetition authorities keep such <strong>in</strong>formation confidential, which is a positivepo<strong>in</strong>t (Article 56(3) of the <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong>ter alia). Special procedures are providedfor <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g such <strong>in</strong>formation at trials to protect the confidentiality ofbus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong>formation.www.images.comENFORCEMENT OF THE COMPETITION LAW AGAINST RBPs<strong>Competition</strong> authorities should f<strong>in</strong>d it easier to obta<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>formallyif they make it known that they are required to keep bus<strong>in</strong>ess secrets confidentialand they have demonstrated that they comply with the requirement ofconfidentiality. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, for a new competition authority, it is important tobuild trust with the bus<strong>in</strong>ess community; but it is also helpful if the authority<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 49


ENFORCEMENT OF THE COMPETITION LAW AGAINST RBPshas the formal authority to require the submission of the <strong>in</strong>formation. At somepo<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> a competition proceed<strong>in</strong>g, it will be necessary to obta<strong>in</strong> formal records,but <strong>in</strong> mak<strong>in</strong>g the prelim<strong>in</strong>ary determ<strong>in</strong>ation whether an <strong>in</strong>vestigation shouldbe pursued, it may be that the burden on everyone will be less if the <strong>in</strong>terviews<strong>in</strong> a prelim<strong>in</strong>ary <strong>in</strong>vestigation are <strong>in</strong>formal. Many allegations or suspicions ofviolations can be dismissed quickly and at a low cost by us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formal<strong>in</strong>vestigative techniques.Intent evidence: It is often much more difficult to obta<strong>in</strong>. As noted above,evidence that enterprises are parties to illegal agreements is often difficult toobta<strong>in</strong>, especially if there is no confidential <strong>in</strong>formant. An abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ancecase may present the same k<strong>in</strong>d of difficulties <strong>in</strong> obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g adequate proof of aviolation. But obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g such proof is not simply a matter of luck or magic, itis more often the product of <strong>in</strong>tense <strong>in</strong>vestigative work. For example, it mightbe possible to prove that managers of rival firms met regularly <strong>in</strong> secret fromhotel or restaurant records or by credit card or bank<strong>in</strong>g records. Establish<strong>in</strong>g apredatory pric<strong>in</strong>g case generally requires the use of an accountant to showbelow-cost pric<strong>in</strong>g and the use of other <strong>in</strong>vestigators to determ<strong>in</strong>e whether theenterprise was simply elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g excess <strong>in</strong>ventory of discont<strong>in</strong>ued productl<strong>in</strong>es. If we th<strong>in</strong>k of determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g market shares to be like mapp<strong>in</strong>g unknownterritory, we might th<strong>in</strong>k of obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g evidence about <strong>in</strong>tent to be like detectivework. The objective is not usually to obta<strong>in</strong> a confession, but to elim<strong>in</strong>ate thepossibility of <strong>in</strong>nocent explanations for the bus<strong>in</strong>ess events that have occurred.There are occasions <strong>in</strong> which special techniques like the offer of leniency to aco-conspirator or a “dawn raid” on facilities may be the key to establish<strong>in</strong>gviolations.Dawn raids: In the competition world, dawn raids mean those surprise<strong>in</strong>spections carried out by the officials of the competition authorities at thepremises of the bus<strong>in</strong>ess or bus<strong>in</strong>esses suspected, to obta<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>crim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>gevidence. Dawn raids are not too difficult to undertake, and can generallybr<strong>in</strong>g good results, especially <strong>in</strong> the case the alleged companies refuse tocooperate.Though the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> does not specify the use ofdawn raids dur<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>vestigation process over competition cases, the Decree116/2005, under its Article 94 provide for the same. More <strong>in</strong>formation aboutthe necessary techniques to carry out searches, raids and <strong>in</strong>spections <strong>in</strong> generalcan be obta<strong>in</strong>ed from the website of the International <strong>Competition</strong> Network(ICN) at: Leniency: Leniency is a generic term to describe a system of partial or totalamnesty from the penalties that would otherwise be applicable to a cartelmember, which reports its cartel membership to a competition enforcementagency. 53 In addition, agency decisions that could be considered lenienttreatment <strong>in</strong>clude agree<strong>in</strong>g to pursue a reduction <strong>in</strong> penalties or not to refer a50 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


matter for crim<strong>in</strong>al prosecution. The term leniency, thus, could be used to referto total immunity and “lenient treatment”, which means less than full immunity.A leniency policy describes the written collection of pr<strong>in</strong>ciples and conditionsadopted by an agency that govern the leniency process. A leniency policy isone component of a leniency programme, which also <strong>in</strong>cludes <strong>in</strong>ternal agencyprocesses, for example, how the agency implements their leniency policy.Many jurisdictions have developed programmes that offer leniency <strong>in</strong> order toencourage violators to confess and implicate their co-conspirators with firsthand,direct “<strong>in</strong>sider” evidence that provides proof of conduct parties want toconceal. The programmes uncover conspiracies that would otherwise goundetected, can destabilise exist<strong>in</strong>g cartels and can act as a deterrent effect toenter<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to cartel arrangements. The programmes elicit confessions, directevidence about other participants, and leads that <strong>in</strong>vestigators can follow forother evidence too. The evidence can be obta<strong>in</strong>ed more quickly, and at lowerdirect cost, compared to other methods of <strong>in</strong>vestigation, lead<strong>in</strong>g to prompt andefficient resolution of cases. To get this <strong>in</strong>formation, the parties who provide itare promised lower f<strong>in</strong>es, shorter sentences, less restrictive orders, or evencomplete leniency.Some leniency is available <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> <strong>Law</strong>, asprovided under Article 85 of the Decree 116/2005. However, these provisions are at a very<strong>in</strong>itial stage and will be of much help <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>duc<strong>in</strong>gcartelists to come forward and cooperate withthe competition authority. A more properleniency programme, therefore, needs to be builtup <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>. More <strong>in</strong>formation on how to draft<strong>Competition</strong> authoritiesshould build a file, whileobta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g evidence,which <strong>in</strong>cludes proof ofevery element of theviolation.an effective leniency programme aga<strong>in</strong> can be obta<strong>in</strong>ed from the website ofthe International <strong>Competition</strong> Network (ICN)at: 5.3. Preserv<strong>in</strong>g Proof of ViolationsThe idea is that the competition authorities should build a file, while obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gevidence, which <strong>in</strong>cludes proof of every element of the violation. In the US,for example, when an enterprise is first notified that an <strong>in</strong>vestigation has been<strong>in</strong>itiated, the enterprise is told that it is forbidden by law from destroy<strong>in</strong>g anydocuments that may relate to the <strong>in</strong>vestigation. At an appropriate time, thisevidence should be collected <strong>in</strong> a manner, which is both admissible <strong>in</strong> acompetition hear<strong>in</strong>g and, if possible, <strong>in</strong> a form that cannot be denied by theenterprises charged with a competition violation. For example, the request ordemands for <strong>in</strong>formation and documents always require that the submitt<strong>in</strong>genterprise <strong>in</strong>clude a certification by an authorised official that the submissionconta<strong>in</strong>s all the documents requested (or certified copies of them) and thatthese are unaltered documents. Written submissions and oral testimony is swornunder penalty of perjury.ENFORCEMENT OF THE COMPETITION LAW AGAINST RBPs<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 51


ENFORCEMENT OF THE COMPETITION LAW AGAINST RBPsThe <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> deals with this issue very briefly <strong>in</strong> itsArticle 60, which only def<strong>in</strong>es what evidences are. However, the Decree 116/2005 devotes an entire section with 11 articles to the issue of “f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g proof/evidence” (Section 5, Article 74-84). Especially, Article 82 of the Decree talksabout preservation of evidence which has been filed, though of course onedoes not expect techniques for preservation to be mentioned here.52 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


6. MERGERS & ACQUISITIONSThe phrase ‘mergers and acquisitions’or ‘M&A’ refers to the aspect ofcorporate f<strong>in</strong>ance strategy andmanagement deal<strong>in</strong>g with the merg<strong>in</strong>g andacquir<strong>in</strong>g of different companies as wellas other assets. 546.1. Dist<strong>in</strong>ction between M&AsAlthough they are often uttered <strong>in</strong> the samebreath and used as though they weresynonymous, the terms M&A mean slightlydifferent th<strong>in</strong>gs.www.images.comWhen one company takes over another and clearly established itself as thenew owner, the purchase is called an acquisition. From a legal po<strong>in</strong>t of view,the target company ceases to exist, and the buyer “swallows” the bus<strong>in</strong>ess.In the pure sense of the term, a merger happens when two firms agree to goforward as a s<strong>in</strong>gle new company rather than rema<strong>in</strong> separately owned andoperated. For example, both Daimler-In <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese law, M&Acases are called as‘economicconcentration’, which<strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong>ter aliamergers, acquisitions,jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures, andconsolidations.2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> def<strong>in</strong>es them as follows:Benz and Chrysler ceased to exist whenthe two firms merged, and a newcompany, DaimlerChrysler, wascreated. 55In <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese law, M&A cases arecalled as ‘economic concentration’,which <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong>ter alia mergers,acquisitions, jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures, andconsolidations. The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>“1. Merger of enterprises means an act whereby one or several enterprisestransfer all of its/their property, rights, obligations and legitimate <strong>in</strong>tereststo another enterprise and at the same time term<strong>in</strong>ate the existence of themerged enterprise(s).2. Consolidation of enterprises means an act whereby two or more enterprisestransfer all of their property, rights, obligations and legitimate <strong>in</strong>terests toform a new enterprise and, at the same time, term<strong>in</strong>ate the existence of theconsolidated enterprises.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 53


MERGERS & ACQUISITIONS3. Acquisition of enterprises mean an act whereby an enterprise acquires thewhole or part of property of another enterprise sufficient to control ordom<strong>in</strong>ate all or one of the trades of the acquired enterprise.4. Jo<strong>in</strong>t venture between enterprises means an act whereby two or moreenterprises jo<strong>in</strong>tly contribute part of their property, rights, obligations andlegitimate <strong>in</strong>terests to the establishment of a new enterprise.” 566.2. Varieties of M&AsMergers can be characterised accord<strong>in</strong>g tothree categories: horizontal mergers, whichtake place between firms that are actual orpotential competitors occupy<strong>in</strong>g similarpositions <strong>in</strong> the cha<strong>in</strong> of production; verticalmergers, which take place between firms atdifferent levels <strong>in</strong> the cha<strong>in</strong> of production (suchas between manufacturers and retailers); andother mergers, such as those which take placebetween companies that sell the same products<strong>in</strong> different markets (market-extension mergers), or companies sell<strong>in</strong>g differentbut related products <strong>in</strong> the same market (product-extension mergers), orconglomerates with different types of bus<strong>in</strong>esses.www.images.comAn acquisition may be only slightly different from a merger. In fact, it may bedifferent <strong>in</strong> name only. Like mergers, acquisitions are actions through whichcompanies seek economies of scale, efficiencies and enhanced market visibility.Unlike all mergers, all acquisitions <strong>in</strong>volve oneUnlike all mergers, allacquisitions <strong>in</strong>volve onefirm purchas<strong>in</strong>g another– there is no exchange ofstock or consolidation asa new company.firm purchas<strong>in</strong>g another – there is no exchangeof stock or consolidation as a new company.In an acquisition, a company can buy anothercompany with cash, stock or a comb<strong>in</strong>ation ofthe two. Another possibility, which is common <strong>in</strong>smaller deals, is for one company to acquire allthe assets of another company. Company X buysall of Company Y’s assets for cash, which means that Company Y will haveonly cash (and debt, if they had debt before). Of course, Company Y becomesmerely a shell and will eventually liquidate or enter another area of bus<strong>in</strong>ess.6.3. Concerns about M&AsThe review and approval of mergers, acquisitions and other corporatecomb<strong>in</strong>ations (here<strong>in</strong>after referred to as ‘mergers’ for convenience) is normallyentrusted to competition authorities or other relevant branches of governmentsuch as m<strong>in</strong>istries of company affairs or sectoral regulators.Many mergers will have little or no negative impact on competition. Somemergers may be pro-competitive, for example, by enhanc<strong>in</strong>g production54 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


efficiencies result<strong>in</strong>g from economies of scale or scope. Mergers may alsocreate new synergies, lead to <strong>in</strong>novation by comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g talents of different firms,and provide additional resources to develop new products and services.Concerns about mergers, acquisitions and other corporate comb<strong>in</strong>ations aregenerally based on the same concerns about anticompetitive behaviour asdiscussed earlier <strong>in</strong> this paper. The ma<strong>in</strong> concern is that a larger merged firmmay <strong>in</strong>crease its market power. To the extent a merged firm becomes moredom<strong>in</strong>ant <strong>in</strong> a market, there is a greater potential to abuse the accumulationand exercise of market power to the detriment of competitors and consumers.In practice, merger reviews and the exercises of related powers by competitionauthorities are usually based on an evaluation of the impact of specific mergeron competition <strong>in</strong> the relevant markets.As will be discussed <strong>in</strong> subsequent sections on cross-border competitionconcerns, at times, a merger might not, by itself, be competition-problematiqueat home, but might affect its subsidiaries <strong>in</strong> a develop<strong>in</strong>g country. However,despite the fact that such merg<strong>in</strong>g of subsidiaries has apparent negative effectson the competitive process of host countries, competition authorities of hostcountries can do very little to regulate a fait accompli merger (see Box 21 foran example).MERGERS & ACQUISITIONSConcerns aboutmergers, acquisitionsand other corporatecomb<strong>in</strong>ations aregenerally based on thesame concerns aboutanticompetitivebehaviour.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, certa<strong>in</strong> M&A cases (or‘economic concentration’, as <strong>in</strong> the<strong>Law</strong>’s words) ‘shall be prohibited if thecomb<strong>in</strong>ed market shares of participat<strong>in</strong>genterprises ... account for over 50percent on the relevant market’, exceptfor cases when ‘one or more of theparticipants … is/are <strong>in</strong> danger ofdissolution or bankruptcy, or ‘theeconomic concentration has an effect of expand<strong>in</strong>g export or contribut<strong>in</strong>g tosocio-economic development, technical and technological advance’, or ‘thecase where enterprises, after implement<strong>in</strong>g economic concentration, are stillof small or medium size as prescribed by law’. 576.4. Merger ReviewLarge merger cases require prior review and approval <strong>in</strong> many jurisdictions.As part of their review, competition authorities may prohibit mergers or approvethem subject to conditions. Mergers are usually only prohibited or subjectedto conditions if the authority concludes that the merger will ‘substantially harmcompetition’. Given the discretion <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terpretation of this threshold,various competition authorities have published merger guidel<strong>in</strong>es. These are<strong>in</strong>tended to assist firms and their advisers to anticipate the procedures andcriteria that will be applied <strong>in</strong> assess<strong>in</strong>g a merger.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 55


MERGERS & ACQUISITIONSAn example of such guidel<strong>in</strong>es isconta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the HorizontalMerger Guidel<strong>in</strong>es published <strong>in</strong>1997 by the US Department ofJustice (DoJ) and the FTC. TheGuidel<strong>in</strong>es set out a five-stageanalysis of the follow<strong>in</strong>g subjectareas: 58l market def<strong>in</strong>ition;l identification of firmsparticipat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the relevant market and their market shares;l identification of potential adverse effects of the merger;l analysis of barriers to market entry; andl evaluation of any efficiencies aris<strong>in</strong>g from the merger.Further details about <strong>in</strong>vestigative techniques recommended for use dur<strong>in</strong>gthe merger review process can be found at the website of the ICN, at:.6.5. Information <strong>in</strong> Merger ReviewAs part of the merger review process, the merg<strong>in</strong>g firms must normally provide<strong>in</strong>formation to the review<strong>in</strong>g authority. It is standard practice <strong>in</strong> jurisdictions,which impose merger review, to require parties to be merger to submit advancenotice of the proposed transaction. The <strong>in</strong>formation disclosed <strong>in</strong> the pre-mergernotification will normally be used by a competition authority <strong>in</strong> the first stageof merger review (i.e. to determ<strong>in</strong>e if any anticompetitive concerns are presentand whether to proceed with a more detailed review of the proposedtransaction). 59www.images.comMergers are usually onlyprohibited or subjectedto conditions if theauthority concludes thatthe merger will‘substantially harmcompetition’.56 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>In <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese <strong>Law</strong>, pre-mergernotification is required ‘if enterprisesparticipat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> economic concentrationhave comb<strong>in</strong>ed market shares of between30 and 50 percent on the relevantmarket’. ‘Where comb<strong>in</strong>ed marketshares of enterprises participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>economic concentration are lower than30 percent on the relevant market orwhere enterprises, after implement<strong>in</strong>geconomic concentration, are still of small or medium size as prescribed bylaw, such notification is not required’. 60These provisions create a design flaw that will impair the workability of the<strong>Law</strong>. How does a company know what its market share is for any of its products?Suppose only one or two products of a company that makes 20 products havea 30 percent market share and those two products only have a greater than 30percent share only <strong>in</strong> two small local markets. Does the enterprise file a prior


notification only for those products andonly for those markets? In short, thisobligation to file a notification seems torequire any firm hav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>tention tomerge with or acquire another firm tohave knowledge about the relevantproduct or geographic markets or thetotal sales <strong>in</strong> those markets; andconsequently their <strong>in</strong>dividual orcomb<strong>in</strong>ed market shares. Relevantmarkets are virtually impossible toIn <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese law, premergernotification isrequired ‘if enterprisesparticipat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>economic concentrationhave comb<strong>in</strong>ed marketshares of between 30and 50 percent on therelevant market’.def<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the abstract, and even <strong>in</strong> context, the merg<strong>in</strong>g parties are frequentlynot go<strong>in</strong>g to know whether they need to notify the competition authorities,whether they need an exemption or are subject to merger controls, etc. This isthe worst foot<strong>in</strong>g that a law could start with. Bus<strong>in</strong>esses must know if theyBox 19: Merger Led to Monopoly <strong>in</strong> the Cable TV SectorThe nation-wide cable television service <strong>in</strong> Thailand became a monopolistic<strong>in</strong>dustry, <strong>in</strong> February 1998, as the two operators, the InternationalBroadcast<strong>in</strong>g Corporation (IBC) and the United Television Network (UTV),merged to become one s<strong>in</strong>gle entity – the United Broadcast<strong>in</strong>g Corporation(UBC).The merger was approved by the Mass Communication Organisation ofThailand (MCOT), the State Enterprise that holds licens<strong>in</strong>g authority <strong>in</strong>Bangkok. The ma<strong>in</strong> justification for the merger was the need for theoperators to consolidate, given the cost hike follow<strong>in</strong>g a sudden sharpdevaluation of the baht <strong>in</strong> June 1997, mark<strong>in</strong>g the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the country’sf<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis that spread globally.In May 1999, UBC raised its monthly subscription fee for its ‘gold package’– i.e. the subscription package with the largest number of channels – by awhopp<strong>in</strong>g 22.47 percent from 890 bahts (US$23) to 1090 (US$28) permonth.An expert sub-committee was established to <strong>in</strong>vestigate whether the cablemonopoly was abus<strong>in</strong>g its market power <strong>in</strong> general, and whether the price<strong>in</strong>crease was excessive. The sub-committee produced an 80-page<strong>in</strong>vestigation report.Later on, the TCC decided that s<strong>in</strong>ce the cable television service is aregulated service, the de facto regulatory body, the MCOT, should handlethe matter, which is responsible for tariff approval and ensur<strong>in</strong>g licensees’compliance to the terms of the licence. The case was, therefore, transferredafter which it was never heard of aga<strong>in</strong>.MERGERS & ACQUISITIONSSource: Cable Television Monopoly Case Study: An Investigation by the Thai Trade<strong>Competition</strong> Commission: Deunden Nikomborirak, Research Director, ThailandDevelopment Research Institute.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 57


MERGERS & ACQUISITIONShave obligations. Here they will not know until the litigation is f<strong>in</strong>ished atwhich po<strong>in</strong>t they may be liable for large penalties even though they had noidea that they are covered. That after-the-fact determ<strong>in</strong>ation of the law’scoverage will underm<strong>in</strong>e its credibility.The content of pre-merger notifications is generally def<strong>in</strong>ed by the law orregulation. Required <strong>in</strong>formation typically <strong>in</strong>cludes:l identity of the firms <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> the proposed transaction;l description of the nature and commercial terms of the transaction;l tim<strong>in</strong>g of the transaction;l f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>formation on the <strong>in</strong>volved (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g revenue, assets and copiesof annual or other f<strong>in</strong>ancial reports);l identification of related ownership <strong>in</strong>terests and the organisation structureof the firms <strong>in</strong>volved; andl description of the relevant product and service markets <strong>in</strong> which the firmsoperate.The <strong>in</strong>itial <strong>in</strong>formation fil<strong>in</strong>g typically triggers a wait<strong>in</strong>g period, dur<strong>in</strong>g whichthe review<strong>in</strong>g authority will be entitled to request further <strong>in</strong>formation. Thisprocess concludes with a determ<strong>in</strong>ation by the review<strong>in</strong>g authority whether toproceed with a more detailed <strong>in</strong>vestigation.If the competition authority decides to proceed with a further <strong>in</strong>vestigation, itwill obta<strong>in</strong> more <strong>in</strong>formation from the merger participants. Additional<strong>in</strong>formation is usually gathered from third parities such as competitors andcustomers. Commercially sensitive <strong>in</strong>formation is also generally protected frompublic disclosure.Dur<strong>in</strong>g a more detailed review, a competition authority will normally seek<strong>in</strong>formation about matters such as the follow<strong>in</strong>g:l products, customers, suppliers, market shares, f<strong>in</strong>ancial performance;l activity of competitors and competitors’ market shares;l availability of substitute products;l <strong>in</strong>fluence of potential competition (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g foreign competition);l pace of technological or other change <strong>in</strong> the relevant markets, and its impacton competition;l nature and degree of regulation <strong>in</strong> the relevant markets; andl quality of a merger review will depend heavily on the quality and range of<strong>in</strong>formation available to the review<strong>in</strong>g authority.6.6. Merger RemediesThe goal of merger control law is to prevent or remove anticompetitive effectsof mergers. Three types of remedies are typically used to achieve this goal.Prohibition or Dissolution: The first remedy <strong>in</strong>volves prevent<strong>in</strong>g the merger<strong>in</strong> its entirety, or if the merger has been previously consummated, requir<strong>in</strong>gdissolution of the merged entity.58 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Partial Divestiture: A second remedy is partial divestiture. The merged firmmight be required to divest assets or operations sufficient to elim<strong>in</strong>ate identifiedanticompetitive effects, with permission to proceed with the merger <strong>in</strong> otherrespect.The goal of mergercontrol laws is toprevent or removeanticompetitive effectsof mergers. Three typesof remedies are typicallyused to achieve thisgoal.Regulation/Conditional Approval: Athird remedy is regulation ormodification of the behaviour of themerged firm <strong>in</strong> order to prevent or reduceanticompetitive effects. This can beachieved through a variety of one-timeconditions and ongo<strong>in</strong>g requirements.The first two remedies are structural, andthe third remedy is behavioural.Behavioural remedies require ongo<strong>in</strong>g regulatory oversight and <strong>in</strong>tervention.Structural remedies are often more likely to be effective <strong>in</strong> the long run andrequire less ongo<strong>in</strong>g government <strong>in</strong>tervention.Box 20: South African Pharma Mergers: Conditions for AspenMERGERS & ACQUISITIONSAspen Pharmacare (Pty) Limited, a generic drugs firm was a protagonistof two merger cases, both conditionally approved by the <strong>Competition</strong>Commission <strong>in</strong> South Africa. In the first case it acquired one of its smallerdirect competitors, Triomed. Based on an <strong>in</strong>ternationally accepted criterionof def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g relevant markets of pharmaceutical products, it was found thatthere were 26 product overlaps between the two firms. The divestiture ofTetracycl<strong>in</strong>e products by Aspen was stipulated as the condition ofauthoris<strong>in</strong>g the merger.In the second Aspen case, the South African subsidiary of the mult<strong>in</strong>ationalpharmaceutical firm GlaxoSmithKl<strong>in</strong>e expressed its <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> acquir<strong>in</strong>gthe company. The merger took place <strong>in</strong> a fast chang<strong>in</strong>g market environment,at a time when a new market regulation was be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>troduced forpharmaceutical products. This new regulation elim<strong>in</strong>ated a significant partof the sales marg<strong>in</strong>s charged by wholesale firms, it created an <strong>in</strong>centivesystem for replac<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>novative drugs with generic ones and, <strong>in</strong> general, it<strong>in</strong>troduced a so-called transparent pric<strong>in</strong>g system. It may be supposed thatthe merger was, at least <strong>in</strong> part, <strong>in</strong>itiated by the mult<strong>in</strong>ational firm <strong>in</strong> orderto get a better competitive position on the domestic market of generic drugs.The conditional authorisation of the merger affected only the sales of onespecific product (Lanox<strong>in</strong>). It stipulated no divestiture as such but just thecondition that this product may not be part of the transaction.Source: Adam Torok (2005), <strong>Competition</strong> Policy Reform <strong>in</strong> South Africa – Towards theMa<strong>in</strong>stream CP Model for ‘Transition’ Economies <strong>in</strong> the Third World, Budapest, p. 39.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 59


MERGERS & ACQUISITIONSBox 21: The Rothmans of Pall Mall/ British AmericanTobacco Merger <strong>in</strong> ZimbabweIn January 1999, British American Tobacco Plc of the United K<strong>in</strong>gdomannounced that it had reached an agreement with the shareholders ofRothmans International, Compagnie F<strong>in</strong>anciere Richemont AG ofSwitzerland and Rembrandt Group Limited of South Africa to merge their<strong>in</strong>ternational tobacco bus<strong>in</strong>esses. Subsequent to the completion of the<strong>in</strong>ternational merger between British American Tobacco Plc and RothmansInternational, Rothmans of Pall Mall (Zimbabwe) Limited <strong>in</strong> September1999 applied to the <strong>Competition</strong> Commission of Zimbabwe for authorisationto acquire the entire issued share capital of British American TobaccoZimbabwe Limited.The merg<strong>in</strong>g parties gave as one of the reasons to merge the decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gmarket for cigarettes <strong>in</strong> Zimbabwe. It was presented that the Zimbabweanmanufactured cigarette market had decl<strong>in</strong>ed to such an extent that it wasno longer big enough for the cont<strong>in</strong>ued viability of two manufacturers asevidenced by the poor performance of British American Tobacco ZimbabweLimited <strong>in</strong> its f<strong>in</strong>ancial year ended December 31, 1998.The case was evaluated as a horizontal merger as def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> section 2 ofthe <strong>Competition</strong> Act.The Commission noted that although the merger would result <strong>in</strong> a creationof a monopoly situation <strong>in</strong> the relevant market (i.e. the manufacturedcigarette market), it had other public <strong>in</strong>terest benefits provided for <strong>in</strong> the<strong>Competition</strong> Act. The fail<strong>in</strong>g firm defence put forward by the merg<strong>in</strong>gparties was also considered a strong po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> support of the merger.The Commission therefore authorised the merger with certa<strong>in</strong> conditionsaimed at alleviat<strong>in</strong>g the adverse effects of the monopoly situation created.The conditions related to the disposal of surplus cigarette mak<strong>in</strong>g equipmentto third parties <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> enter<strong>in</strong>g the Zimbabwean cigarette mak<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>dustry, and surveillance by the <strong>Competition</strong> Commission of future cigaretteprice <strong>in</strong>creases while the monopoly situation created rema<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> existence,with any price rises be<strong>in</strong>g justified to the Commission before be<strong>in</strong>g effected.Source: Alexander J Kububa, Issues In Market Dom<strong>in</strong>ance: Merger Control In Zimbabwe,paper presented at the World Bank’s Regional Conference on <strong>Competition</strong> Policy,Competitiveness, and Investment <strong>in</strong> A Global Economy, Dar-es-Salaam, Tanzania: 10–12May 2004.Partial divestiture or behavioural constra<strong>in</strong>ts are less <strong>in</strong>trusive <strong>in</strong>to the operationof market than prevent<strong>in</strong>g a merger from proceed<strong>in</strong>g or requir<strong>in</strong>g dissolutionof a previously completed merger. Partial divesture can reduce or elim<strong>in</strong>ateanticompetitive effects while preserv<strong>in</strong>g some of the commercial advantagesof a merger. Partial divestiture is emerg<strong>in</strong>g as a preferred remedy <strong>in</strong> manyjurisdictions.60 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


In <strong>Vietnam</strong>, if an M&A case is found to be <strong>in</strong> violation of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>2004, i.e. the parties to the merger have a comb<strong>in</strong>ed market share of more than50 percent <strong>in</strong> the relevant market and the merger is not eligible for exemptionunder the law, 61 then ‘division or split the merged or consolidated enterprises;or forced resale of the acquired enterprise parts’ will be the applicableremedies. 62Further details about remedies recommended for use by competition authoritiescan be found at the website of the ICN, at.6.7. Jo<strong>in</strong>t VenturesIn some cases, exist<strong>in</strong>g competitors <strong>in</strong> a market may decide to enter <strong>in</strong>to a jo<strong>in</strong>tventure. The competition analysis of jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures generally raises similarissues to those discussed under the section of restrictive agreements, andtherefore would normally violate per se competition rules. The process and<strong>in</strong>formation requirements for review of a jo<strong>in</strong>t venture, however, shouldresemble those discussed earlier <strong>in</strong> this section on M&As.MERGERS & ACQUISITIONSThe reasons for this recognition may be importantto understand. Jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures create less economicconcentration than mergers, therefore there issome economic policy reason to prefer or at leastnot discrim<strong>in</strong>ate aga<strong>in</strong>st lesser concentrations ofeconomic power. While that seems logical,competition laws did not develop that waybecause jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures are commonly horizontalagreements between competitors that elim<strong>in</strong>atecompetition between them. Mergers of coursedo the same th<strong>in</strong>g but it was assumed that mergersalways conta<strong>in</strong> some efficiencies. Thus, <strong>in</strong> thebeg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g, jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures are allowed only if theywere necessary to create the venture, which means neither company alonecould undertake the new project.http://venture2.typeped.comJo<strong>in</strong>t ventures createless economicconcentration thanmergers, therefore thereis some economic policyreason to prefer or atleast not discrim<strong>in</strong>ateaga<strong>in</strong>st lesserconcentrations ofeconomic power.Over time, however, the focusshifted from the need forcooperation between thecompetitors to the question ofwhether there are economic sav<strong>in</strong>gsfrom the jo<strong>in</strong>t venture and, if therewere, then the jo<strong>in</strong>t venture wouldbe held lawful if it would be allowedas a merger (mean<strong>in</strong>g if thecomb<strong>in</strong>ation of the two companieswould leave enough companies <strong>in</strong>the market to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> competition).<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 61


MERGERS & ACQUISITIONSBox 22: Jo<strong>in</strong>t Distribution of Polyethylene CoversA Request for Exemption from Court Approval for Agreement to EstablishPoligar was made to the Antitrust Authority of Israel <strong>in</strong> 1994 to approve amarket<strong>in</strong>g jo<strong>in</strong>t venture between the only two Israeli producers ofpolyethelene covers.In analys<strong>in</strong>g the effects of the proposed venture, the General Directorstressed the discipl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g effects of potential and exist<strong>in</strong>g imports, on themarket power of the domestic firms. He approved the venture s<strong>in</strong>ce it wouldenable the domestic firms to reduce their costs and thus compete moreeffectively with foreign importers, without harm<strong>in</strong>g the Israeli consumer.This reason<strong>in</strong>g differs significantly from that on which past decisions toapprove jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures was based. Whereas, <strong>in</strong> the past, emphasis was placedon the ability of the parties to the venture to reduce their costs without areal analysis of total welfare effects, the decision <strong>in</strong> Poligar approves theventure based on the need of the parties to act more efficiently <strong>in</strong> order tomeet foreign competition.The analysis ensures that the Israeli consumer, as well as the Israeli firms,will enjoy the benefits of the venture. This sort of analysis, which givesmuch weight to competitive considerations, based on market conditions,and evaluates the effects of the conduct on all market players, characterisesmost of the decisions from the 90’s onwards.Source: Gal & Israeli (2006), Israel, <strong>Competition</strong> Regimes <strong>in</strong> the World – A Civil SocietyReport, CUTS, p. 69.62 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


7. UNFAIR TRADE PRACTICES:COMPETITION & CONSUMERPROTECTIONThe complementarities between competitionand consumer protection is no longer a newand debatable issue <strong>in</strong> any discussionperta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g to competition law, but rather asettled one. 63<strong>Competition</strong> presses producers to offer themost attractive price and quality options. Incompetitive markets, producers must ga<strong>in</strong> newsales, new clientele by satisfy<strong>in</strong>g consumerneeds by <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the range of choicesavailable, s<strong>in</strong>ce if consumers dislike theoffer<strong>in</strong>gs of one seller, they might turn to others. This is because the availabilityof substitutable goods at acceptable prices <strong>in</strong> competitive markets enablesconsumers to shift purchase, which pushes each seller to try to satisfy consumerpreferences.Further than <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the choices available to consumers, <strong>in</strong> competitivemarkets, long-term competitive strategies make it imperative for producers toprovide correct and useful <strong>in</strong>formation about their products, to fulfill promisesconcern<strong>in</strong>g price, quality, and other terms of sale, and thus to improve theirimage toward the consumers. Thus, <strong>in</strong> its mandate of ensur<strong>in</strong>g the marketsfunction competitively, competition law becomes an effectively tool to promoteconsumer welfare, which is also the objective of consumer protection policy.<strong>Consumer</strong> protection policy works to ensure that consumers can make well<strong>in</strong>formeddecisions about their choices and that sellers will fulfil their promisesabout the products they offer. In other words, consumer protection policyprevents producers from engag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> unfair practices while seek<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>creasetheir sales.UTPs not only harm the consumers, but also harm other market players <strong>in</strong> theprocess, and more importantly, they harm the market as a whole as well. 64Revelations that they are cheated by a producer, a group of bus<strong>in</strong>esses mightlead the consumers to distrust an entire <strong>in</strong>dustry or market, which <strong>in</strong> turn willaffect sales <strong>in</strong> that market negatively. In a way, while prevent<strong>in</strong>g and punish<strong>in</strong>g<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 63


UNFAIR TRADE PRACTICES: COMPETITION & CONSUMER PROTECTIONUTPs, consumer protection policy does more than safeguard<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>terestsof the consumers or promot<strong>in</strong>g consumer welfare, it comes back to facilitatecompetition.7.1. Unfair Trade PracticesUTPs encompass a broad array of torts,all of which <strong>in</strong>volve economic <strong>in</strong>jurybrought on by deceptive or wrongfulconduct. The legal theories that can beasserted <strong>in</strong>clude claims such as tradesecret misappropriation, unfaircompetition, false advertis<strong>in</strong>g, palm<strong>in</strong>goff,dilution and disparagement. UTPscan arise <strong>in</strong> any field of technology andfrequently appear <strong>in</strong> connection with theUTPs can arise <strong>in</strong> anyfield of technology andfrequently appear <strong>in</strong>connection with themore traditional<strong>in</strong>tellectual propertyclaims of patent,trademark and copyright<strong>in</strong>fr<strong>in</strong>gement.more traditional <strong>in</strong>tellectual property claims of patent, trademark and copyright<strong>in</strong>fr<strong>in</strong>gement.Specific types of UTPs prohibited <strong>in</strong> domestic law depend on the law of aparticular country. The World Bank (WB) and Organisation for EconomicCooperation and Development (OECD) Model <strong>Law</strong>, for example, lists thefollow<strong>in</strong>g trade practices to be unfair: 65l distribution of false or mislead<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation that is capable of harm<strong>in</strong>gthe bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong>terests of another firm;l distribution of false or mislead<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation to consumers, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g thedistribution of <strong>in</strong>formation lack<strong>in</strong>g a reasonable basis, related to the price,character, method or place of production, properties, and suitability foruse, or quality of goods;www.images.comwww.images.com64 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


lllfalse or mislead<strong>in</strong>g comparison of goods <strong>in</strong> the process of advertis<strong>in</strong>g;fraudulent use of another’s trade mark, firm name, or product labell<strong>in</strong>g orpackag<strong>in</strong>g; andunauthorised receipt, use or dissem<strong>in</strong>ation of confidential scientific,technical, production, bus<strong>in</strong>ess or trade <strong>in</strong>formation.The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> call these practices ‘unfair competitionacts’, i.e. ‘competition acts performed by enterprises <strong>in</strong> the process of do<strong>in</strong>gbus<strong>in</strong>ess, which run counter to common standards of bus<strong>in</strong>ess ethics and causedamage or can cause damage to the State’s <strong>in</strong>terests, legitimate rights and<strong>in</strong>terests of other enterprises or consumers’. 66 These acts <strong>in</strong>clude:(i) mislead<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dications;(ii) <strong>in</strong>fr<strong>in</strong>gement upon others’ trade secrets;(iii)constra<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess;Box 23: Mislead<strong>in</strong>g Advertis<strong>in</strong>g & Bait-and-SwitchUTPs, which are now exclusively with<strong>in</strong> the scope of the <strong>Consumer</strong>Protection Act of India (COPRA), were brought under the purview of theMRTP Act <strong>in</strong> August 1984. The first sales promotion organiser to be chargedunder the Act was Bal Krishna Khurana, who was famous, <strong>in</strong> all of NorthIndia, for sell<strong>in</strong>g ‘export quality’ hosiery goods at ridiculously low prices.CUTS reacted accord<strong>in</strong>gly when Khurana hit Jaipur <strong>in</strong> 1984 to sell hisgoods at throwaway prices. CUTS had been receiv<strong>in</strong>g compla<strong>in</strong>ts from alarge number of victims of these sales and decided to <strong>in</strong>vestigate.Consequently, CUTS moved the MRTPC aga<strong>in</strong>st Khurana and demandedto know how he could offer ‘export quality’ hosiery goods, worth Rs 210,for as low as Rs 5 to15.In its compla<strong>in</strong>t before the Commission, CUTS stated that mislead<strong>in</strong>gadvertisement and bait-and-switch sell<strong>in</strong>g, that followed, caused harm and<strong>in</strong>convenience to the public and buyers. Visits to Khurana’s stalls causedmental agony to consumers as what they took home were ma<strong>in</strong>ly bogusgoods after wast<strong>in</strong>g time and money.The MRTPC promptly ordered an <strong>in</strong>quiry <strong>in</strong>to the compla<strong>in</strong>t, which wasfollowed by an order restra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Khurana from organis<strong>in</strong>g any more salespromotion ventures.Furthermore, the MRTPC advised newspapers not to carry mislead<strong>in</strong>gadvertisements, as one of the duties of the media is to protect consumerrights, and not solely earn revenue through bogus advertisements. Thenewspapers responded to the advice. Even so, after a gap of a few years,sadly, newspapers cont<strong>in</strong>ue to carry such advertisements.UNFAIR TRADE PRACTICES: COMPETITION & CONSUMER PROTECTIONSource: Mehta, Pradeep S, How To Survive As A <strong>Consumer</strong>, CUTS, 1998.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 65


UNFAIR TRADE PRACTICES: COMPETITION & CONSUMER PROTECTIONBox 24: Giant Supermarkets Misled <strong>Consumer</strong>s <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>aIn April 2002, the implement<strong>in</strong>g authority of the Commercial Loyalty Actcondemned Wal-Mart Argent<strong>in</strong>a SA for violation of Article 9 of Bill 22.802,which prohibited mislead<strong>in</strong>g publicity and promotion of goods and services.Throughout 2002, it was the norm for big supermarket cha<strong>in</strong>s (Wal-Mart,Carrefour, to name a few) to offer products at special prices to attract customers.However, when the time to pay the bill came, <strong>in</strong> many cases customersfound out that the price charged for some of the products weredifferent than the one announced either on the brochures or the stand.In the case under review, the implement<strong>in</strong>g authority decided to regulatethe price of several products of the basic food basket. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>spection,it found differences of over eight percent <strong>in</strong> two of the products chosen.Prices shown <strong>in</strong> the brochure or at the stand were less than the onef<strong>in</strong>ally charged at the counter.The severity of the sanction took <strong>in</strong>to account the fact that Wal-Mart hadalready been penalised for the same type of <strong>in</strong>fraction more than 30 times<strong>in</strong> the period of three years.Source: Andrea Botto (2006), Argent<strong>in</strong>a, <strong>Competition</strong> Regimes <strong>in</strong> the World – A Civil SocietyReport, CUTS, p. 544.(iv) discredit<strong>in</strong>g other enterprises;(v) disturb<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess activities of other enterprises;(vi) advertis<strong>in</strong>g for the purpose of unfair competition;(vii) sale promotion for the purpose of unfair competition;(viii) discrim<strong>in</strong>ation by associations; and(ix) illicit multi-level sale, etc. 677.2. Mislead<strong>in</strong>g Advertis<strong>in</strong>gMislead<strong>in</strong>g advertis<strong>in</strong>grefers to any false ormislead<strong>in</strong>g representationthat is made to the publicby a person <strong>in</strong> the courseof bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Therepresentation may beabout the nature, characteror performance of aproduct, such as size, typeof contents or weight. Italso <strong>in</strong>cludes warranties,statements, or guarantees that are not based on adequate and proper tests. 68www.cartoonstock.com66 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


A clear example of mislead<strong>in</strong>gadvertis<strong>in</strong>g is an advertisement, whichdescribes a pair of shoes, which was“Made <strong>in</strong> Taiwan” as “EnglishHandmade”. Through the use of anexpression associated with a long historyof quality shoes, the merchant had madea misrepresentation as to the type of shoethat was be<strong>in</strong>g sold. Another example ofmislead<strong>in</strong>g advertis<strong>in</strong>g occurs when amerchant makes a promise to a consumer to deliver an item <strong>in</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong> numberof days and does not fulfill this promise. Failure to disclose <strong>in</strong>formation, whichis material to the consumer’s purchas<strong>in</strong>g decision, will also amount tomislead<strong>in</strong>g advertis<strong>in</strong>g.The essence of apyramid scheme is thatthe profit of the bus<strong>in</strong>esscomes from the sale offranchises, not the saleof products eitherbecause there are noproducts or the productsare not saleable at aprice that would makethe <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> thefranchise profitable.Mislead<strong>in</strong>g advertis<strong>in</strong>g is prohibitedunder Article 45 of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, together withcomparative advertis<strong>in</strong>g and imitation ofothers’ advertis<strong>in</strong>g products. Hopefully,when the <strong>Law</strong> is fully enforced, it willhelp to eradicate such practices, whichare quite prevalent <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>. For<strong>in</strong>stance, many consumers <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>compla<strong>in</strong>ed about their sad experienceswith a shampoo brand called CLEAR,which is certified by some ELIDAInstitute (Paris) to be able to elim<strong>in</strong>atedandruff with<strong>in</strong> seven times ofshampoo<strong>in</strong>g, accord<strong>in</strong>g to the advertisement, though of course, this miracle doesnot happen <strong>in</strong> real life, though CLEAR does help a bit <strong>in</strong> dandruff controll<strong>in</strong>g 69In addition to mislead<strong>in</strong>g advertisement, other unfair and deceptive tradepractices are also fully def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> and prohibited by the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004of <strong>Vietnam</strong>. Hereafter, we choose to discuss further only another type of UTP,which is also very prevalent <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>, andhas caused tremendous harm to consumer:illegal multi-level market<strong>in</strong>g - pyramidschemes.7.3. Pyramid SchemesPyramid schemes, or alsoreferred to as “cha<strong>in</strong>referral”, “b<strong>in</strong>arycompensation” or “matrixmarket<strong>in</strong>g” schemes, is anon-susta<strong>in</strong>able bus<strong>in</strong>essMislead<strong>in</strong>g advertis<strong>in</strong>g isprohibited under Article45 of the <strong>Competition</strong><strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>,together withcomparative advertis<strong>in</strong>gand imitation of others’advertis<strong>in</strong>g products.www.content.answers.comUNFAIR TRADE PRACTICES: COMPETITION & CONSUMER PROTECTION<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 67


UNFAIR TRADE PRACTICES: COMPETITION & CONSUMER PROTECTIONBox 25: Multi-level Market<strong>in</strong>g Firm Faces Fraud ProbeThe HCM City Department of Trade has recently proposed fraud <strong>in</strong>vestigatorsto launch a probe <strong>in</strong>to possible irregularities, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g trade fraud,at multi-level market<strong>in</strong>g firm S<strong>in</strong>h Loi. The department earlier undertook atwo-month <strong>in</strong>vestigation <strong>in</strong>to the operations of S<strong>in</strong>h Loi and announced itsresults at a meet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> mid June 2006, with a representative of the MLMcompany and the HCM City <strong>Consumer</strong> Protection Association attend<strong>in</strong>g.A month before, the Department of Trade temporarily revoked the multilevelmarket<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration certificate of S<strong>in</strong>h Loi as its <strong>in</strong>spectionteam found signs of the company <strong>in</strong>fr<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g regulations on taxes, documentation,promotions, goods labell<strong>in</strong>g and network market<strong>in</strong>g. At themeet<strong>in</strong>g, S<strong>in</strong>h Loi’s representative objected to the withdrawal of the certificate,say<strong>in</strong>g it is abid<strong>in</strong>g by law and fight<strong>in</strong>g the case to the end.Eight companies have been allowed to engage <strong>in</strong> this bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity <strong>in</strong>the city s<strong>in</strong>ce when the Government Decree No. 110/2005ND-CP that allowsfor multi-level sales came <strong>in</strong>to force early this year. S<strong>in</strong>h Loi, whichwas established <strong>in</strong> 2000 with total registered capital of VND2bn, has morethan 100 staff and over 26,000 associates.In the meantime, other MLM companies <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> are also fac<strong>in</strong>g allegations,and accord<strong>in</strong>gly, <strong>in</strong>vestigations from relevant State agencies, creat<strong>in</strong>ga complete chaos <strong>in</strong> this <strong>in</strong>dustry. For <strong>in</strong>stance, a former agent of the LoHoi Trad<strong>in</strong>g Company said that the sell<strong>in</strong>g prices of Lo Hoi were always 5-7 times higher than the average price levels on the market. For example,Lo Hoi sold a multivitam<strong>in</strong> box at VND400,000, while the same product ispriced at less than VND100,000 on the market.Such companies, like Lo Hoi, have successfully attracted many agents becausepeople thought that they would be able to buy products at wholesaleprices, which are much lower than the official retail prices. For example, aproduct, coded as 015, was sold at the retail price of VND432,000/unit,while the wholesale price is VND303,000/unit only.Source: http://english.vietnamnet.vn/biz/2006/08/603121/ et al.model that <strong>in</strong>volves the exchange of money primarily for enroll<strong>in</strong>g other people<strong>in</strong>to the scheme, usually without any product or service really be<strong>in</strong>g delivered.There are other commercial models us<strong>in</strong>g cross-sell<strong>in</strong>g such as multi-levelmarket<strong>in</strong>g (MLM), which are perfectly legal and susta<strong>in</strong>able. 70 Most pyramidschemes take advantage of confusion between genu<strong>in</strong>e bus<strong>in</strong>esses andcomplicated but conv<strong>in</strong>c<strong>in</strong>g moneymak<strong>in</strong>g scams. The essence of a pyramidscheme is that the profit of the bus<strong>in</strong>ess comes from the sale of franchises, notthe sale of products either because there are no products or the products are68 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


not saleable at a price that would make the <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> the franchise profitable.The reason they are called pyramid schemes is that at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g the firstlevels of franchisees can and do make money because <strong>in</strong> addition to sell<strong>in</strong>gsome products, they are also able to sell 10 franchises to friends. In order forthese ten franchisees to make money they will each have to sell ten franchises(or a total of a hundred). For those hundred to make money they will have tosell a thousand franchises. And those thousand will have to sell 10,000franchises, and so on.The evil is not the sale of the franchise or even the payment of a f<strong>in</strong>der’s fee tothe franchisee who signs up new franchisees. The evil is that <strong>in</strong>formation aboutthe profitability of the sale of the basic product is mislead<strong>in</strong>g. At no level is thesale of this product profitable. The bus<strong>in</strong>ess seems to be profitable to prospectivefranchise buyers because the person sell<strong>in</strong>g them the franchises are mak<strong>in</strong>gmoney from the sale of new franchises. But as the numbers above illustrate thenumbers of new buyers of franchises quickly escalates to impossibly largenumbers. This would be clear if the orig<strong>in</strong>ators of the franchise showed howmany products had to be sold to make the franchise profitable and what thelikelihood is of be<strong>in</strong>g able to make that many sales.In <strong>Vietnam</strong>, the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 (Art. 48) and its subord<strong>in</strong>ate DecreeNo. 110/2005/ND-CP expla<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> details the differences between MLM andpyramid sell<strong>in</strong>g, and sets out the responsibilities for operators and participants<strong>in</strong> these types of plans. MLM, when it operates with<strong>in</strong> the limits set by the law,is a legal bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity, while pyramid sell<strong>in</strong>g is a MLM plan that<strong>in</strong>corporates various deceptive market<strong>in</strong>g practices, mak<strong>in</strong>g it a serious offence.It is illegal to:l request those who wish to participate <strong>in</strong> the market<strong>in</strong>g scheme to pay adeposit, buy an <strong>in</strong>itial volume of goods or pay a sum of money for the rightto participate <strong>in</strong> the multi-level sale network;l not commit to buy back goods at 90 percent at least of the price at whichthe goods were sold to participants for re-sale;l give participants commissions, bonuses or other economic benefits whichare ga<strong>in</strong>ed mostly from the enticement of other people to participate <strong>in</strong> themulti-level sale network; andl supply false <strong>in</strong>formation on the benefits of the participation <strong>in</strong> the multilevelsale network, false <strong>in</strong>formation on the nature and utilities of goods <strong>in</strong>order to entice the participation of other people.UNFAIR TRADE PRACTICES: COMPETITION & CONSUMER PROTECTION<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 69


8. CROSS-BORDER ISSUESWith the open<strong>in</strong>g up of domestic markets to foreign competition, countrieshave become <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly susceptible to anticompetitive practices that orig<strong>in</strong>ateoutside their own territory. 71 The types of cross-border anticompetitive practicesare quite similar to that of those perpetrated with<strong>in</strong> national borders. The onlydifference lies <strong>in</strong> the cross-border (<strong>in</strong>ternational) dimensions of theanticompetitive behaviour. A number of areas where these behaviours areperceived to give rise to competition concerns with <strong>in</strong>ternational dimensionsare discussed here. Though there is no s<strong>in</strong>gle way by which one can estimatethe damage that these cross-border anticompetitive practices are caus<strong>in</strong>g.However, one can have a fair understand<strong>in</strong>g of the nature and dimensions ofthe problems through the analysis of anecdotal evidence. These issues canbroadly be classified <strong>in</strong>to four groups: 72l market power <strong>in</strong> global or export markets;l barriers to import competition;l foreign <strong>in</strong>vestment related; andl IPRs related.8.1. Market Power <strong>in</strong> Global or Export MarketsInternational cartels, export cartels and related arrangements can be <strong>in</strong>cludedunder this category, together with multi-jurisdictional M&As, abuse ofdom<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong> overseas markets, cross-border predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g and pricediscrim<strong>in</strong>ation.Several <strong>in</strong>ternational cartels, most of which wereconstituted by producers from <strong>in</strong>dustrialisedcountries, were uncovered <strong>in</strong> the 1990s. Thesecartels were found to have severely affected the<strong>in</strong>ternational trade flows dur<strong>in</strong>g this period,significantly raised the prices of goods traded,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g imports <strong>in</strong>to low-<strong>in</strong>come countries.Develop<strong>in</strong>g countries’ imports of cartelisedgoods <strong>in</strong> 1997, for example, amounted toUS$81.1bn, which represents 6.7 percent of thesecountries’ imports and 1.2 percent of their national <strong>in</strong>comes.www.rohan.sdsu.eduCartelisation, however, is not only about loss <strong>in</strong> consumer welfare; it alsohampers the development of poor countries, and growth of their firms, <strong>in</strong> severalways. Various techniques, rang<strong>in</strong>g from the threat of retaliatory price wars, useof common sales or distribution agency, to patent pool<strong>in</strong>g, were used by<strong>in</strong>ternational cartels to block develop<strong>in</strong>g-country competitors’ entry <strong>in</strong>to therelevant markets.70 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Box 26: The Graphite Electrodes Cartel and its Effectson Develop<strong>in</strong>g Country Steel ProducersGraphite electrodes are used primarily <strong>in</strong> the production of steel <strong>in</strong> electricarc furnaces. In a highly concentrated world market, two firms (one Germanand one American) had a comb<strong>in</strong>ed market share of roughly two-thirds atthe beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 1990s. Japanese producers supply a considerable partof the rema<strong>in</strong>der, with modest contributions from a number of smallerproducers based <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, pr<strong>in</strong>cipally India and Ch<strong>in</strong>a.All of the major producers <strong>in</strong> this market operate production facilities <strong>in</strong> anumber of countries, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g develop<strong>in</strong>g countries such as Brazil, Mexico,South Africa, Russia, and Poland, and sell their products throughout theworld.The OECD estimates that, “the cartel affected US$5-7bn <strong>in</strong> sales worldwide.Throughout the world, the cartel resulted <strong>in</strong> price <strong>in</strong>creases fromroughly US$2000 per metric tonne to US$3200-US$3500 <strong>in</strong> variousmarkets”.CROSS-BORDER ISSUESThe only direct estimate of pecuniary harm caused to purchasers <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries comes from the Korea Fair Trade Commission(KFTC), which <strong>in</strong> March 2002 convicted six graphite electrodemanufactures from the US, Germany, and Japan. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to KFTC,Korean steel manufactures “imported graphite electrodes amount<strong>in</strong>g toUS$553mn from the six companies from May 1992 to February 1998, anddur<strong>in</strong>g the period the import price <strong>in</strong>creased from an average of US$2,225per ton <strong>in</strong> 1992 to an average of US$3,356 <strong>in</strong> 1997 (about 48.9 percentprice <strong>in</strong>crease). The damage <strong>in</strong>curred by the companies import<strong>in</strong>g graphiteelectrodes is estimated at approximately US$139mn. Korea’s major<strong>in</strong>dustries such as automobile and shipbuild<strong>in</strong>g that consume much steelwere also <strong>in</strong>fluenced by this <strong>in</strong>ternational cartel”.Source: Evenett, Simon J. (2003), Study on Issues Relat<strong>in</strong>g To A Possible MultilateralFramework on <strong>Competition</strong> Policy, WTO Document No. WT/WGTCP/W/228.Also a type of collusive agreements by producers to exercise market power <strong>in</strong>foreign markets, export cartels, however, are ‘restra<strong>in</strong>ts on trade’ officiallyCartelisation, however, isnot only about loss <strong>in</strong>consumer welfare; it alsohampers thedevelopment of poorcountries, and growth oftheir firms, <strong>in</strong> severalways.sanctioned by many governments whofollow a ‘beggar-thy-neighbour’ policyby permitt<strong>in</strong>g their private firms tocartelise, as long as affected markets areoutside the country. 73Large companies merge <strong>in</strong> the developedworld and consequently theirsubsidiaries and associates <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries too end up <strong>in</strong> new<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 71


CROSS-BORDER ISSUEScomb<strong>in</strong>ations. This can create positionof dom<strong>in</strong>ance for merg<strong>in</strong>g firms, hav<strong>in</strong>gImport cartels formed bya potential of subsequent abuse.domestic importers orMoreover, develop<strong>in</strong>g countries maybuyers, and similaralso be affected by M&A activities thatarrangements may be atake place outside their territory, andthreat to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gaffect their local subsidiaries. Thecompetition <strong>in</strong> a market.Zimbabwe tobacco merger casepresented <strong>in</strong> Box 20 provides a good example <strong>in</strong> this regard.Other than collusion or comb<strong>in</strong>ations, the size and scope of transnationalcompanies (TNCs) make it possible for them to engage <strong>in</strong> a variety ofanticompetitive practices. Take the example of Microsoft. The company hasbeen hauled up for <strong>in</strong>dulg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> anticompetitive practices time and aga<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> theUS and the EU. By and large, it has not faced such action <strong>in</strong> other jurisdictions,especially <strong>in</strong> the develop<strong>in</strong>g world, where the effects of Microsoft’s conducthave been <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g at the same pace as its bus<strong>in</strong>ess.8.2. Barriers to Import <strong>Competition</strong>Import cartels, vertical market restra<strong>in</strong>ts creat<strong>in</strong>g import barriers, privatestandard sett<strong>in</strong>g activities, abuse of monopsonistic dom<strong>in</strong>ance, etc, may fallunder this category. Import cartels formed by domestic importers or buyers,and similar arrangements may be a threat to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g competition <strong>in</strong> a market.In pr<strong>in</strong>ciple, a national competition law may normally be able to tackle suchmarket-access barriers to foreign supplies and suppliers, though <strong>in</strong> practicethose barriers have been very much deliberately tolerated. In some cases, importcartels were allowed to counter export cartels.A well known example <strong>in</strong> this regard is the dispute between Japan and the USwhere it was alleged that Fuji effectively prevented Kodak’s exports to theJapanese market by controll<strong>in</strong>g the distribution channel. In the early 1990s,such concerns prompted a revision of US guidel<strong>in</strong>es regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>ternationalenforcement to permit application of the US antitrust laws to foreign-basedactivities such as import cartels that restrict US producers’ access to foreignmarkets.8.3. Foreign Investment-related <strong>Competition</strong> IssuesForeign <strong>in</strong>vestment has always been recognisedas hav<strong>in</strong>g complex effects on host countries’market structure and competition. M&As, <strong>in</strong>particular, can be used to reduce competitionvia “monopolis<strong>in</strong>g M&As”, which can occurwhen:l The acquir<strong>in</strong>g firm was export<strong>in</strong>gsubstantially to a market before it buys acompet<strong>in</strong>g firm there;www.images.com72 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


lllA foreign firm with an affiliate, already<strong>in</strong> the market, acquires another, therebyacquir<strong>in</strong>g a dom<strong>in</strong>ant or monopolisticmarket share;The <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g TNC acquires a marketleader with which it had previouslycompeted; andThe acquisition is <strong>in</strong>tended to suppressrather than develop the competitivepotential of the acquired firm.Foreign <strong>in</strong>vestment hasalways been recognisedas hav<strong>in</strong>g complexeffects on hostcountries’ marketstructure andcompetition.While these monopolis<strong>in</strong>g M&As’ adverse effects on a host country’s marketstructure and competition can be tackled if the host country has an adequatelegal framework to impose some remedies, as what happened <strong>in</strong> many cases <strong>in</strong>the developed world, evidence <strong>in</strong> this l<strong>in</strong>e rema<strong>in</strong>s anecdotal <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries.In India, for <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong> 1994, H<strong>in</strong>dustan Lever Limited (HLL), the Indiansubsidiary of Unilever, acquired its ma<strong>in</strong> local rival, Tata Oil Mills Company(TOMCO), to assume a dom<strong>in</strong>ant position <strong>in</strong> the toilet soap (75 percent) anddetergent (35 percent) markets. 74 The proposed merger had been challengedby the HLL Employees’ Union on various grounds, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g that the mergerwould result <strong>in</strong> a large share of the market be<strong>in</strong>g controlled by a TNC, and thatconsumers’ <strong>in</strong>terests might be adversely affected. However, no measures havebeen undertaken s<strong>in</strong>ce the 1991 amendment of India’s then competition law,the MRTP Act 1969, had unfortunately removed the need for approval ofmergers, acquisitions and takeovers <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g “large” and/or “dom<strong>in</strong>ant”firms. 75 After that, HLL also acquired several local companies <strong>in</strong> other markets,such as the ice cream makers Dollops,Kwality and Milkfood. This raised itsmarket share <strong>in</strong> the ice cream market fromzero <strong>in</strong> 1992-1993 to 69 percent <strong>in</strong> 1996-1997 and over 74 percent <strong>in</strong> 1997-1998. 768.4. IPRs-related <strong>Competition</strong> IssuesWithout a suitable and strong legalframework <strong>in</strong> place to check theanticompetitive behaviour of IPR holders,the possibility that TNCs will be tempted to abuse their market power cannotbe ruled out. To make matters worse, though the Trade Related Aspects ofIntellectual Property Rights (TRIPs) Agreement enables the broad frameworkfor countries to take necessary action if an IPR is abused, lead<strong>in</strong>g toanticompetitive outcomes, it does not ‘empower’ every country to do so. Forexample, <strong>in</strong> cases where there are disparities <strong>in</strong> the barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g power betweenthe ‘guilty’ – which is often giant TNCs, and the ‘law-enforcer’ – when theyare develop<strong>in</strong>g countries with weak enforcement capacity and small markets,it would be hard to discipl<strong>in</strong>e IPR abuses. In another case, the suggested remedywww.images.comCROSS-BORDER ISSUES<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 73


CROSS-BORDER ISSUESThe TRIPs Agreementenables the broadframework forcountries to takenecessary action if anIPR is abused,lead<strong>in</strong>g toanticompetitiveoutcomes, it does not‘empower’ everycountry to do so.of compulsory licens<strong>in</strong>g would not beavailable to a country that does not havedomestic production capacity, except <strong>in</strong>the case of pharmaceutical products.8.5. Deal<strong>in</strong>g with Cross-borderIssues under the <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>Whether it is to deal with anticompetitivepractices that occur at national level, orthose that have <strong>in</strong>ternational dimensions,hav<strong>in</strong>g a strong and well-oiledcompetition regime is an essentialprerequisite. Even so, a strongcompetition regime, at national levels, may not be enough to tackle crossborderanti-competitive practices. It is recommended that provisions for extraterritorialjurisdiction be adopted to legally empower competition authorities<strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries to deal with such cases.The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, as well as its implementationregulations, does not deal with any of the cross-border issues. The only foreignelement dealt with by these provisions occurs when one of the parties tocompetition cases is a foreign-<strong>in</strong>vested enterprise, based and operat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong><strong>Vietnam</strong> (Art. 2(1) of the <strong>Law</strong>).This is quite a big constra<strong>in</strong>t of the laws because of the fact that <strong>Vietnam</strong> isactively open<strong>in</strong>g its economy and <strong>in</strong>tegrat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to the global economy. Pend<strong>in</strong>gits accession <strong>in</strong>to the WTO, which also means most of the protectionist measurescurrently exist<strong>in</strong>g would be removed, enterprises <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> will have to facewith not only the competitive pressure from with<strong>in</strong> and outside the country,but anticompetitive conducts orig<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g from outside as well.Besides, with the physical borders <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly tumbl<strong>in</strong>g down due toglobalisation and <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>tegration, bus<strong>in</strong>ess transactions are no longerbound with<strong>in</strong> the territory of a certa<strong>in</strong> country. Numerous global and regionaldeals are be<strong>in</strong>g concluded everywhere. In this context, whereas the foreigncounterparts can count on their national or regional (for <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong> the case ofEU) competition authorities, <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese enterprises would be left withoutshelter <strong>in</strong> any antitrust case, if the dealor transaction is concluded outside theterritory of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, or if theircounterpart does not have a physicalpresence <strong>in</strong> the country.Last but not the least, with globalcompetition cases, which have seriousconsequences on trade, economies, andA strong competitionregime, at nationallevels, may not beenough to tackle crossborderanticompetitivepractices.74 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Box 27: International Patent <strong>Law</strong>s Hurt Develop<strong>in</strong>g CountriesIn South Africa <strong>in</strong> 1998, approximately one <strong>in</strong> five adults is liv<strong>in</strong>g withHIV/AIDS. S<strong>in</strong>ce 1996, the world has known that “cocktails” ofantiretroviral drugs save lives. They are not a cure for AIDS, but here theyhave turned it <strong>in</strong>to an almost chronic disease, ak<strong>in</strong> to diabetes. The rate ofAIDS deaths <strong>in</strong> the US was plummet<strong>in</strong>g, but <strong>in</strong> South Africa, no one exceptthe exceed<strong>in</strong>gly rich could afford the drugs. In the US, taxpayers subsidisethe cost of the drugs, which cost around US$15,000 per year. In SouthAfrica, mak<strong>in</strong>g treatment universally available at such prices would havebankrupted the government. But it was not the drugs themselves that wereexpensive - it was the patents.The South African government was <strong>in</strong> a b<strong>in</strong>d. South Africa has a strongpatent system - the legacy of apartheid, but also the result of pressure fromcountries like the US. Affordable drugs existed, but not for them. So, <strong>in</strong>1998, they did what any responsible government would do: They passed alaw that would give them the power to br<strong>in</strong>g drug prices down. The lawwould have allowed them to “parallel import” cheaper medic<strong>in</strong>es, which iscompletely legal under the TRIPs Agreement, to take advantage of the factthat patented drugs are sold at different prices <strong>in</strong> different countries.CROSS-BORDER ISSUESFaced with a potential public health crisis, the US Congress recognisedwhat many other countries have been argu<strong>in</strong>g all along: that patents are not“rights” but rather privileges – and that they do not come before the rightsto health and life. But that is not how they – or the drug <strong>in</strong>dustry – approachedthe issue when it came to South Africa. The possibility that South Africa –a t<strong>in</strong>y percentage of the world’s drug market – might start us<strong>in</strong>g genericdrugs was treated as a colossal threat to the <strong>in</strong>terests of the USpharmaceutical <strong>in</strong>dustry. It did not matter that the US had signed the TRIPsagreement <strong>in</strong> 1994, recognis<strong>in</strong>g that develop<strong>in</strong>g country governments havethe ability to do just what the US could do and had done <strong>in</strong> similar cases.And it didn’t matter that literally millions of lives were at stake. Accord<strong>in</strong>gto Charlene Barshefsky, the US Trade Representative at the time: “We allmissed it.... I didn’t appreciate at all the extent to which our <strong>in</strong>terpretationof South Africa’s <strong>in</strong>ternational property obligations was draconian”.Activists around the world realised it, and mobilised aga<strong>in</strong>st the lawsuitwith slogans like “Patient Rights over Patent Rights”, and “Stop MedicalApartheid”. In March 2001, when the case f<strong>in</strong>ally reached the courtroom,the drug companies, fear<strong>in</strong>g the public relations backlash, withdrew theirsuit.Source: Kapczynski (2002), Strict International Patent <strong>Law</strong>s Hurt Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries,YaleGlobal Onl<strong>in</strong>e at http://yaleglobal.yale.edu/display.article?id=562.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 75


CROSS-BORDER ISSUESconsumers all over the globe (such as those of <strong>in</strong>ternational cartels, or crossborderM&As etc), <strong>Vietnam</strong> as a country and <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese consumers wouldnot be able to assert their legitimate rights and <strong>in</strong>terests and redeem any damagedone on them.In this regard, it is important to note that the competition regime of <strong>Vietnam</strong> isstill very young and under severe resource and capacity constra<strong>in</strong>ts, whichwould make it impossible at this stage for them to discipl<strong>in</strong>e huge mult<strong>in</strong>ationalcompanies or <strong>in</strong>vestigate/enforce cases with cross-border elements. However,hav<strong>in</strong>g extra-territorial jurisdiction would help this young competition authorityto challenge conduct which may have an effect <strong>in</strong> the domestic market. It wouldalso be useful for <strong>Vietnam</strong> to enter <strong>in</strong>to cooperation, understand<strong>in</strong>g oragreements with their counterpart agencies to garner <strong>in</strong>formation of suchconduct. The adoption of such provisions deal<strong>in</strong>g with cross-border issuesshould be a priority for <strong>Vietnam</strong> <strong>in</strong> the future.76 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


9. COMPETITION LAW VSINTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAWSIPRs protection is a policy tool meant to foster<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>novation; which benefitsconsumers through the development of new and improved goods and services,and spurs susta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g economic growth. It bestows on <strong>in</strong>novators the right tolegitimately exclude, for a limited amount of time, other parties from the benefitsaris<strong>in</strong>g from new knowledge, and more specifically, from the commercial useof <strong>in</strong>novative products and processes based on that new knowledge. In otherwords, <strong>in</strong>novators or IPR holders are rewarded with a temporary monopoly bythe law to recoup thecosts <strong>in</strong>curred <strong>in</strong> the<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> vs. IP <strong>Law</strong>sresearch and <strong>in</strong>novationprocess and earnrightful and reasonableprofits, so that theyhave <strong>in</strong>centives to<strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> furtherresearch and<strong>in</strong>novation.<strong>Competition</strong> law, on the other hand, has always been regarded by most asessential <strong>in</strong> curb<strong>in</strong>g market distortions, discipl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g anticompetitive practices,prevent<strong>in</strong>g monopoly and abuse of monopoly, <strong>in</strong>duc<strong>in</strong>g optimum allocation ofresources and benefit<strong>in</strong>g consumers with fair prices, wider choice and betterqualities. It, therefore, ensures that the monopolistic power associated withIPRs is not excessively compounded or leveraged and extended to the detrimentof competition. Further, while seek<strong>in</strong>g to protect competition and thecompetitive process, which <strong>in</strong> turn prod <strong>in</strong>novators to be the first <strong>in</strong> the marketwith a new product or service at a price and quality that consumers want,competition law underscores the importance of stimulat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>novation ascompetitive <strong>in</strong>puts, and thus also works to enhance consumer welfare.Thus, it is now generally recognised that the goals of competition law and IPlaw are rather complementary and mutually re<strong>in</strong>forc<strong>in</strong>g. They share the commonpurpose of promot<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>novation, enhanc<strong>in</strong>g and benefit<strong>in</strong>g customer welfareas well as allocat<strong>in</strong>g efficient economic resources. Moreover, they are alsodifferent levels of market regulation. Errors or systematic biases <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>terpretation or application of one policy’s rules can harm the other policy’seffectiveness. A challenge for both policies is to f<strong>in</strong>d the proper balance ofcompetition and <strong>in</strong>novation protection.www.witi.ael.be<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 77


COMPETITION VS INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW9.1. IPRs Standards as <strong>Competition</strong>RegulationIPRs policy acts as an <strong>in</strong>stitutionalframework regulation for the properoperation of markets for <strong>in</strong>tangiblesubject matter, and is therefore exemptfrom antitrust control. <strong>Competition</strong> lawof most countries, therefore, expresslyor implicitly exempt from theirIPRs policy acts as an<strong>in</strong>stitutional frameworkregulation for the properoperation of markets for<strong>in</strong>tangible subject matter,and is therefore exemptfrom antitrust control.application the exclusive rights <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>tellectual property protectiongranted by the state, which are considered to justify restrictions that wouldotherwise be subject to competition scrut<strong>in</strong>y.The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, similarly, also gives exemption tocompetition restra<strong>in</strong>ts, which “promote technical and technological advances,rais<strong>in</strong>g goods and service quality”. 77 Economic concentration cases, whichwill otherwise be prohibited by the law, will also be exempted if they contributeto ‘technical and technological advance’. 789.2. Regulation of the Exercise of IPRs through <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>As a piece of <strong>in</strong>dividual property, IPRs are fully subject to general competitionpr<strong>in</strong>ciples, when they are exercised or put <strong>in</strong>to commercial use <strong>in</strong> the market.<strong>Competition</strong> law, thus, while hav<strong>in</strong>g no impact on the very existence of IPRs,operates to conta<strong>in</strong> the exercise of the property rights with<strong>in</strong> the proper boundsand limits which are <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> the exclusivity conferred by the ownership of<strong>in</strong>tellectual rights. In other words, when the exercise of IPRs gives rise tosome competition concerns, competition law will have a role to play.The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> does not deal with competition restra<strong>in</strong>tscaused due to the exercise of IPRs <strong>in</strong> an explicit manner, though it does providefor unfair competition acts associated with the <strong>in</strong>fr<strong>in</strong>gement of <strong>in</strong>tellectualproperty, such as trade secrets, trademarks and brand names. 79 However, itsprohibition towards various competition-restrict<strong>in</strong>g agreements, abuse ofdom<strong>in</strong>ant position and abuse of monopoly position implicitly cover suchpractices, notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g IPRs as an element of the same or not.Moreover, Article 5(1) of the <strong>Law</strong> also stipulates that, ‘where there is anydisparity between the provisions of this <strong>Law</strong> and those of other laws, regard<strong>in</strong>gcompetition restriction acts or unfair competition acts, the provisions of this<strong>Law</strong> shall apply’. This is further enhanced by <strong>Vietnam</strong>’s new <strong>Law</strong> on IPRs,adopted <strong>in</strong> November 2005, to be effective s<strong>in</strong>ce 01 July, 2006 (here<strong>in</strong>afterreferred to as the IPRs <strong>Law</strong> 2005), which says, ‘the exercise of those IPRsshall not violate the <strong>in</strong>terests of the State’s and the public <strong>in</strong>terests, the legitimaterights and <strong>in</strong>terests of other organisations and <strong>in</strong>dividuals,’ legitimate rightsand <strong>in</strong>terests, and shall not violate related laws and regulations’. 8078 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


On the other hand, <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>, before promulgation of the <strong>Vietnam</strong> Civil Codeof October 28, 1995 (here<strong>in</strong>after referred to as the VCC 1995), 81 IPRs hadbeen stipulated separately <strong>in</strong> several subord<strong>in</strong>ate ord<strong>in</strong>ances, namely theIPRs had been stipulatedseparately <strong>in</strong> severalsubord<strong>in</strong>ate ord<strong>in</strong>ances,namely the Ord<strong>in</strong>ance onforeign technologytransfer to <strong>Vietnam</strong> <strong>in</strong>1988, the Ord<strong>in</strong>ance onthe <strong>in</strong>dustrial property <strong>in</strong>1989, and the Ord<strong>in</strong>anceon protection ofcopyrights <strong>in</strong> 1994.Ord<strong>in</strong>ance on foreign technologytransfer to <strong>Vietnam</strong> <strong>in</strong> 1988, theOrd<strong>in</strong>ance on the <strong>in</strong>dustrial property <strong>in</strong>1989, and the Ord<strong>in</strong>ance on protectionof copyrights <strong>in</strong> 1994. Out of the 8 eightparts of the VCC 1995, Part 6 (Art. 745to 825) covered IPRs and technologytransfer, but no specific provisiongoverned the relationship between IPRsand competition. However, <strong>in</strong> the DecreeNo. 45/1998/ND-CP dated July 01, 1998govern<strong>in</strong>g the details of technologytransfer (here<strong>in</strong>after referred to as the TTDecree 1998), some anticompetitiveclauses were listed that could not be <strong>in</strong>corporated <strong>in</strong>to technology transferagreements. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, several restrictive acts were declared illegal, wherethe licensee is forced to do th<strong>in</strong>gs which it would not have been able to do asan <strong>in</strong>dependent person.In the classification of the <strong>in</strong>dustrial property licens<strong>in</strong>g agreements, the IPRs<strong>Law</strong> 2005 recognises exclusive agreements. 82 However, it also states that<strong>in</strong>dustrial property licens<strong>in</strong>g agreements shall not unreasonably restrict thelicensee’s rights. In particular, theyshall not conta<strong>in</strong> restrictive conditionsthat do not derive from the licensor’srights, such as improvement <strong>in</strong> thelicensed property; right to exportgoods; buy<strong>in</strong>g conditions and a nochallengeclause.Licens<strong>in</strong>g constitutes animportant part of theIPRs regime, or to bemore specific, <strong>in</strong>dustrialproperty rights.9.3. <strong>Competition</strong> Concerns <strong>in</strong> Licens<strong>in</strong>g AgreementsAs already stated, licens<strong>in</strong>g constitutes an important part of the IPRs regime,or to be more specific, <strong>in</strong>dustrial property rights. Far from restrict<strong>in</strong>gcompetition, <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple, it extends the opportunities for traders to stimulatethe market, by facilitat<strong>in</strong>g the wider dissem<strong>in</strong>ation of the protected technologies/knowledge as well as products and services us<strong>in</strong>g the protected patent as <strong>in</strong>put.Indeed, what may give a licens<strong>in</strong>g agreement its bus<strong>in</strong>ess-restrictive characterare the specific contractual agreements and market conditions, which createmore or less essential restrictions if the agreement is to have any value. Someof these dimensions:l Territorial restra<strong>in</strong>t;l Exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>g;l Tie-<strong>in</strong>; andl Grant-back.COMPETITION VS INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 79


COMPETITION VS INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAWBox 28: Microsoft’s Abuse of Dom<strong>in</strong>anceMicrosoft is the legitimate owner of the IPRs over the personal computeroperat<strong>in</strong>g system (PC/OS), which is the company’s orig<strong>in</strong>al creation. ThePC/OS is an essential facility both for users to be able to perform applicationssuch as word process<strong>in</strong>g, spreadsheet, etc; and for the application softwaredevelopers to be able to offer a marketable product for users. This enabledMicrosoft to enjoy a monopoly power over licens<strong>in</strong>g the operat<strong>in</strong>g systemsfor PCs (with a 90-percent-plus market share and a substantial applicationsbarrier to entry). Restriction on end-users and monopoly pric<strong>in</strong>g are foundamong the various abusive conducts committed by the software giant.Microsoft does not sell its software to anyone. Instead, it parcels out differentbundles of rights with respect to its software. These rights, which are bundledtogether as a “license,” are the only “products” that Microsoft conveys.Microsoft reta<strong>in</strong>s the title and all rights to its software except for thoserights, which Microsoft expressly conveys through one of these licenses.Microsoft enters one type of license with the orig<strong>in</strong>al equipmentmanufacturers (OEMs). The specified purposes of the license with OEMspermit them ‘to pre-<strong>in</strong>stall [the software] on PCs sold to end users’.On the other hand, Microsoft provides a wholly different license, known asthe end-user license agreement (EULA), to consumers. Microsoft grantsthe right to ‘use the software on the PCs’ to and only to end-users.Microsoft’s end-user license is a take-it-or-leave-it proposition and not aproduct of negotiation. The end users choose to enter the EULA licensewith Microsoft only when they first beg<strong>in</strong> to use the OS, not at the times ofpurchase, payment, or other <strong>in</strong>cidents of the transaction.As a direct result of Microsoft’s restrictive and exclusionary practices, endusers were caused to suffer unique <strong>in</strong>jury. They were deprived of the benefitsof competition, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g but not limited to technological <strong>in</strong>novation, marketchoice, product variety, and substitutable supply.Over time, Microsoft coupled these restrictions with other anticompetitivesteps. These <strong>in</strong>cluded Microsoft’s nearly two-fold <strong>in</strong>crease dur<strong>in</strong>g 1998 ofits prices for licenses of its old and dated (but not obsolete) PC/OS to thesame level of prices charged for licenses of its new PC/OS (from US$49.00to US$89.00).Source: Op<strong>in</strong>ion on the Microsoft Corp. Antitrust Litigation, for the United States DistrictCourt of Maryland, MDL No. 1332, January 2001, by J. Frederick Motz, US District Judge,US District Judge, Op<strong>in</strong>ion on the Microsoft Corp. Antitrust Litigation, for the UnitedStates District Court of Maryland, MDL No. 1332, January 2001.80 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


9.4. IPRs and the Abuse of a Dom<strong>in</strong>ant PositionIPRs, by their very nature, create a form of monopoly or, <strong>in</strong> other words, adegree of economic exclusivity. The creation of that legitimate exclusivity,however, does not necessarily establish the ability to exercise market power oreven <strong>in</strong> case it does confer market power (as already discussed <strong>in</strong> the previouspart), that dom<strong>in</strong>ant position on the market does not by itself constitute an<strong>in</strong>fr<strong>in</strong>gement of the rules on competition law; nor does it impose on the IPRsholders the obligation to license that property to others. Besides, competitionauthorities are normally concerned with the abuse of the dom<strong>in</strong>ant position,whatever the source of such dom<strong>in</strong>ance, rather than with any abuse of IPRs.Much, however, also depends onthe facts of each case <strong>in</strong>volved.Other cases of IPRs-related abuseof dom<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong>clude, some casescan be identified such as:llllMonopoly Pric<strong>in</strong>g: This israrely a serious competitionconcern <strong>in</strong> developedcountries due to theabundance of marketsubstitutes. Meanwhile <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, becausethe number of availablesubstitutes may be morelimited and because most IPR-protected products are owned by foreign<strong>in</strong>terests, monitor<strong>in</strong>g to discipl<strong>in</strong>e monopoly pric<strong>in</strong>g practices by IPRholders is of greater significance.Restrictions on End Users: One very <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g case <strong>in</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t worthwhilemention<strong>in</strong>g to shed some light on restrictions on end users as abuse ofdom<strong>in</strong>ant position is the Microsoft case, which also embodies a monopolypric<strong>in</strong>gdimension (see Box 35).Exclusive Deal<strong>in</strong>g: <strong>Competition</strong>aspects of the limitations on alicensee’s ability to deal <strong>in</strong>competit<strong>in</strong>g technologies will beanalysed on the basis of (i) theduration, (ii) rationale, and (iii)degree of foreclosure caused byrestrictions to rival licensors.Tied Sales: Tie-<strong>in</strong> is generallydeemed per se illegal if (i) it <strong>in</strong>volvestwo separate products or services thatare tied together, (ii) the seller hasIPRs create a form ofmonopoly. Besides,competition authoritiesare normally concernedwith the abuse of thedom<strong>in</strong>ant position,whatever the source ofsuch dom<strong>in</strong>ance, ratherthan with any abuse ofIPRs.www.google.comCOMPETITION VS INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 81


COMPETITION VS INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAWmarket power <strong>in</strong> the ty<strong>in</strong>g product and has the ability to extend this marketpower <strong>in</strong> the tied product, due to favourable market conditions (high entrybarriers etc); (iii) the arrangement has an adverse effect on competition <strong>in</strong>the relevant market for the tied product; and (iv) efficiency justificationsfor the arrangements do not outweigh the anticompetitive effects.9.5. Refusal to DealA widely accepted premise of IP laws is that IP holders are under no obligationto license subject matters protected to others. This pr<strong>in</strong>ciple is generally heldto be true even when a firm is <strong>in</strong> possession of a monopolistic position <strong>in</strong> amarket as a result of its ownership of<strong>in</strong>tellectual property. An early nonantitrustdecision by the US SupremeCourt stated that the ability to excludecompetitors from the use of a new patent‘may be said to have been of the veryessence of the rights conferred by thepatent, as it is the privilege of any ownerof property to use or not use withoutquestion of motive’. 83 On the other hand, from the perspective of IPR/competition law <strong>in</strong>terface, there may be the question of whether such dutyexists.Courts <strong>in</strong> the EU and the US have at times held that refusals to license a patentviolate competition law. However, <strong>in</strong> neither jurisdiction, though they are amongthe most advanced jurisdictions <strong>in</strong> terms of IP and competition law, have theyprovided clear direction as to whether a refusal to deal is anticompetitive whereit <strong>in</strong>volves <strong>in</strong>tellectual property. Slightly different was the case of Brazil, whereArticle 21 of the Antitrust <strong>Law</strong> enlists the “non-exploitation or the <strong>in</strong>adequateuse of <strong>in</strong>tellectual property rights and technology of a company” as a strong<strong>in</strong>dication that the free competition rules have been violated.9.6. Compulsory Licens<strong>in</strong>gA compulsory license is an <strong>in</strong>voluntary contract between a will<strong>in</strong>g buyer andan unwill<strong>in</strong>g seller imposed and enforced by the state. The three most prevalentcompulsory licens<strong>in</strong>g provisions areapplicable where a dependent patent isbe<strong>in</strong>g blocked, where a patent is notbe<strong>in</strong>g worked, or where an <strong>in</strong>ventionrelates to food or medic<strong>in</strong>e. Additionally,compulsory licens<strong>in</strong>g may beimplemented as a remedy <strong>in</strong> antitrust ormisuse situations, where the <strong>in</strong>ventionis important to national defence or wherethe entity acquir<strong>in</strong>g the compulsorylicense is the sovereign. In these cases,the public <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> broader access tothe patented <strong>in</strong>vention is consideredA widely acceptedpremise of IP laws is thatIP holders are under noobligation to licensesubject mattersprotected to others.Compulsory licens<strong>in</strong>gmay be implemented asa remedy <strong>in</strong> antitrust ormisuse situations, wherethe <strong>in</strong>vention isimportant to nationaldefence or where theentity acquir<strong>in</strong>g thecompulsory license isthe sovereign.82 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


more important than the private <strong>in</strong>terest of the right holder to fully exploit hisexclusive rights. The designated third party should generally compensate thepatent holder through payment of remuneration. Compulsory licenses do notdeny patent holders the right to act aga<strong>in</strong>st non-licensed parties.With regard to the IPR/competition <strong>in</strong>terface, compulsory licens<strong>in</strong>g can begranted on the grounds of the existence of: (i) a refusal to license; and(ii) anticompetitive exercises of IPRs by patent holders.Such compulsory licens<strong>in</strong>g is permitted not only <strong>in</strong> the WTO TRIPs Agreementbut also <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Vietnam</strong>-US Bilateral Trade Agreements (BTAs). (Art. 31(c)and 31(k), TRIPs; Article 7.8.K, Chapter II, BTA). The IPRs <strong>Law</strong> 2005 of<strong>Vietnam</strong> also stipulates that compulsory licens<strong>in</strong>g is possible when ‘the person(s)hav<strong>in</strong>g demand to use a patent cannot reach an agreement with the person(s) <strong>in</strong>possession of the exclusive right to use that patent despite try<strong>in</strong>g to negotiate,<strong>in</strong> a sufficient time period, with reasonable prices and commercial terms’ (refusalto license) or ‘the person(s) <strong>in</strong> possession of the exclusive right to use thepatent is/are considered as hav<strong>in</strong>g undertaken RTPs prohibited under laws oncompetition’. 849.7. Parallel ImportAnother issue of the most controversialareas of direct and significant <strong>in</strong>terfacebetween the exercise of IPRs andcompetition law not yet mentioned aboveis parallel import.Parallel imports are goods brought <strong>in</strong>toa country without the authorisation of thepatent, trademark or copyright holdersafter those goods were placedlegitimately <strong>in</strong>to the market elsewhere.Parallel imports aregoods brought <strong>in</strong>to acountry without theauthorisation of thepatent, trademark orcopyright holders afterthose goods were placedlegitimately <strong>in</strong>to themarket elsewhere.Unlike pirated copyright goods or counterfeit trademark goods, parallel importsare legitimate products, as argued by some, s<strong>in</strong>ce the IPR holders have agreedBox 29: Chile Allows Parallel Import to Promote <strong>Competition</strong>COMPETITION VS INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAWMany matters of parallel imports have been brought up before thePreventative Commission of Chile, most of which orig<strong>in</strong>ated as compla<strong>in</strong>tsfrom private parties. Generally, importers have asked the Commission aboutthe legality of import<strong>in</strong>g orig<strong>in</strong>al products, which are already <strong>in</strong> the marketby virtue of a previous distribution agreement. The Preventative Commissionestablished the criteria that the parallel imports of orig<strong>in</strong>al products promotecompetition <strong>in</strong> markets, authoris<strong>in</strong>g them.Source: Gesner Oliviera, Chile, <strong>Competition</strong> Regimes <strong>in</strong> the World – A Civil Society Report,CUTS (2006), p.565.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 83


COMPETITION VS INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAWBox 30: M<strong>in</strong>istry of Health to Regulate ForeignDrugs, Medic<strong>in</strong>e PricesIn early 2004, the M<strong>in</strong>istry of Health of <strong>Vietnam</strong> decided to establish apanel responsible for exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g licence applications to import foreignmedic<strong>in</strong>es that have not yet been registered for distribution <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>.Deputy M<strong>in</strong>ister of Health, Le Ngoc Trong, issued the decision on April20 describ<strong>in</strong>g it as another long-term effort to control foreign drug importsand distributions and as a means of stabilis<strong>in</strong>g domestic drug prices.The panel is to meet at least once a week to check applications for drugimports without registered numbers. It would bear full responsibility fordecisions made at every meet<strong>in</strong>g and must sign the m<strong>in</strong>utes.The policy was one of 18 that the M<strong>in</strong>istry of Health plans to issue beforeJune 2004 to curb ris<strong>in</strong>g drug prices. The new drug import policy wasexpected to allow domestic companies to directly import medic<strong>in</strong>es fromforeign manufacturers if distributors do not, or cannot sufficiently supplythe market or supply at <strong>in</strong>flated prices.Another decree, which would soon be adopted, would allow some domesticcompanies to have ‘parallel import licences’ (mean<strong>in</strong>g they will be allowedto import cheaper brands of drugs now sell<strong>in</strong>g at high prices <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>),for drugs to treat serious diseases when drug manufacturers, distributors orcompanies possess<strong>in</strong>g registered drug trademarks cannot adequately supplythe market, or sell the drugs items at <strong>in</strong>flated prices.This measure is also designed to prevent monopolies from occurr<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> themarket place, Tuu said. In the <strong>in</strong>terim, the M<strong>in</strong>istry will immediately focuson measures to strengthen controls over the import and distribution offoreign drugs, develop new adm<strong>in</strong>istration procedures for pharmacy drugsupplies at all hospitals, fight aga<strong>in</strong>st monopolies, monitor drugprescriptions and sales and strictly enforce punishment regulations.Sources: http://english.vietnamnet.vn/social/2004/04/143011/.to put them <strong>in</strong>to market and thus implicitly authorised their subsequent use, beit be<strong>in</strong>g imported by an unauthorised distributor.Policies regulat<strong>in</strong>g parallel imports stem from specification of the exhaustionof IPRs. The term “exhaustion” refers to the territorial rights of IPR holdersafter the first legitimate sale of their <strong>in</strong>tellectual property-protected products.There are three variants of exhaustion doctr<strong>in</strong>es, namely:l National exhaustion: IPRs end upon first authorised sale with<strong>in</strong> a nationbut IPR owners may prevent parallel trade with other countries.84 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


llBox 31: Importation and Retail<strong>in</strong>g of Compact DiscsThe Australian <strong>Competition</strong> & <strong>Consumer</strong> Commission (ACCC) allegedthe defendants Universal Music, Sony Music and Warner Music and othershad taken unlawful action (threaten<strong>in</strong>g to withdraw significant trad<strong>in</strong>gbenefits from retailers and cutt<strong>in</strong>g off supply to retailers who stocked parallelimports of compact discs) <strong>in</strong> order to discourage or prevent Australianbus<strong>in</strong>esses from sell<strong>in</strong>g competitively priced parallel imports of compactdiscs.The conduct was alleged to constitute a misuse of market power andexclusive deal<strong>in</strong>g prohibited by the Trade Practices Act of Australia. Seniorexecutives were alleged to have been <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> the conduct.The Full Court of the Federal Court upheld an appeal by Universal andWarner that their conduct did not breach the misuse of market powerprovision but confirmed that the conduct did breach the exclusive deal<strong>in</strong>gprovisions.The Full Court also upheld the ACCC’s appeal on penalty <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g thetotal penalties from about US$760,231.59 to over US$1,520,786.52mn.Source: Proceed<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong>stituted <strong>in</strong> September1999 – For summary of allegations, see http://www.accc.gov.au/content/<strong>in</strong>dex.phtml/itemId/322787.Regional exhaustion: IPRs are exhausted upon first authorised sale <strong>in</strong> aparticular region only.International exhaustion: IPRs are exhausted upon first sale anywhere andparallel imports are permitted (also referred to as the “doctr<strong>in</strong>e of firstsale”).Treatment and op<strong>in</strong>ions on parallel imports vary widely. For example, Japanpermits parallel imports <strong>in</strong> patented and trademarked goods unless contractprovisions explicitly bar them or unless their orig<strong>in</strong>al sale was subject to foreignprice regulation. The US policy on parallel imports is mixed, by whichrestrictions on parallel imports exist only for certa<strong>in</strong> types of goods.COMPETITION VS INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAWNo multilateral b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g agreements have ever directly addressed the issue ofparallel imports; neither the TRIPs Agreement nor the 1996 World IntellectualProperty Organisation (WIPO) Copyright Treaty; leav<strong>in</strong>g countries to dealwith the issue <strong>in</strong> the manner they feel appropriate. Article 6 of the TRIPsspecifically states that: “noth<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this Agreement shall be used to address theissue of the exhaustion of IPRs”.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 85


10. ESSENTIAL ELEMENTSFOR SUCCESSBuild<strong>in</strong>g an effective competition regime <strong>in</strong> the context ofdevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries is not a easy job. The dearth of expertiseon competition issues as well as the newness of the samemakes the mere task of draft<strong>in</strong>g a good and appropriatelegislation a huge challenge. Furthermore, even after the lawhas been drafted with much thought and caution, there is stillno guarantee that it will meet its aims.10.1. Sequenc<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> ImplementationToward such success, one of the useful suggestions made so far is to establisha competition authority with a phased approach, which may be appropriate tothe design and implementation of a competition law. 85 The sequenc<strong>in</strong>g illustratedbelow is a ref<strong>in</strong>ed version based upon a presentation made by Gesner Oliviera(former chairman of the Brazilian <strong>Competition</strong> Agency) at a CUTS meet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>2002. He developed this on a simple idea <strong>in</strong>spired by World Bank’s ShyamKhemani and Mark Dutz. 86Given its limited resources and novelty, a competition authority should startwith actions which will most likely benefit the market and build its ownacceptability. Gradually it would <strong>in</strong>troduce measures, which require moresophisticated cost/benefit analysis. Merger review comes after conduct controldue to the fact that the welfare effect of a merger might be less clear than thatof price fix<strong>in</strong>g or collusion, the latter be<strong>in</strong>g positively welfare dim<strong>in</strong>ish<strong>in</strong>g andeasily identifiable by the polity and public.A competition authoritywith a phased approach,which may beappropriate to the designand implementation of acompetition law.Development is a cont<strong>in</strong>uum, and thestages will never be all this clear, and <strong>in</strong>some cases different priorities will beappropriate. In some economies,especially those that have a legacy ofstate-owned or other dom<strong>in</strong>ant firms like<strong>Vietnam</strong>, abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ance/monopolisation might also require apriority similar to that given to horizontalrestra<strong>in</strong>ts. 87 However, <strong>in</strong> exercis<strong>in</strong>g its powers to tame public sector monopolies,the authority has to do it slowly rather than follow the rule book. This is because,while people as consumers would like some restra<strong>in</strong>t on public sector’santicompetitive and anti-consumer behaviour, the establishment feels86 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


I. StartTable 1. Different Stages of Institutional Developmentof National <strong>Competition</strong> Regimes1. <strong>Competition</strong>advocacy andpublic education2. Control ofhorizontalrestra<strong>in</strong>ts3. Check<strong>in</strong>g abuseof dom<strong>in</strong>ance4. Exceptions andexemptions,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g onpublic <strong>in</strong>terestgrounds5. TechnicalassistanceII. Enhancement6. Merger control7. Vertical restra<strong>in</strong>ts8. Development ofthe effectsdoctr<strong>in</strong>eIII. Advancement9. Regulation10. InternationalcooperationarrangementsIV. Maturity11. Secondgeneration<strong>in</strong>ternationalarrangements12. Pro-activecompetitionadvocacySource: Mehta, Pradeep S (2003), Friends of <strong>Competition</strong> – How to Build an Effective<strong>Competition</strong> Regime <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g and Transition Economies, CUTS, India, p.20ESSENTIAL ELEMENTS FOR SUCCESSsubconsciously threatened when action is taken aga<strong>in</strong>st them. This is oftenreflected <strong>in</strong> public support, often orchestrated by politicians and trade unions,that it is people who are be<strong>in</strong>g penalised when public sector firms are upbraided.Often these are l<strong>in</strong>ked to privatisation fears and that also to foreign companies.The stages suggested are organised accord<strong>in</strong>g to the degree of difficulty acompetition authority might face <strong>in</strong> do<strong>in</strong>g a cost-benefit analysis of the impactof competition measures on social welfare. However, it might well be arguedthat legally sound prosecution of price collusion turns out to be more difficultthan a merger review. In fact, it is generally easy to establish the ill effects of acollusive behaviour but often difficult to prove <strong>in</strong> a court of law, due to lack oflegally-sound and solid evidence. Therefore, the actual plan should take <strong>in</strong>toaccount the damage caused to the economy and consumers of a particular anticompetitiveact, but also the chances of success and the expected return on themoney spent <strong>in</strong> pursu<strong>in</strong>g the case, given the relative probabilities of successthrough other l<strong>in</strong>es of action or public policies.10.2. Build<strong>in</strong>g a Healthy <strong>Competition</strong> CultureThe second, though no less important, key to successful implementation of acompetition law is to build up a healthy competition culture. Creat<strong>in</strong>g a healthy<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 87


ESSENTIAL ELEMENTS FOR SUCCESScompetition culture depends on effectiveimplementation of the competition lawand a supportive policy environment.There are a number of factors thatcontribute to (though also have thepotential to underm<strong>in</strong>e) the successfulenforcement of a competition law, which<strong>in</strong>clude: 88l power conferred on the competitionauthority;lll<strong>in</strong>dependence from political <strong>in</strong>terference;political support for competition goals; andavailability of resources.Creat<strong>in</strong>g a healthycompetition culturedepends on effectiveimplementation of thecompetition law and asupportive policyenvironment.10.2.1. Power Conferred on the <strong>Competition</strong> AuthorityInstitutional framework: For the competition authority to function properly, itis important that it has the right powers, which <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong>vestigative andadjudicative ones. The <strong>in</strong>vestigative power, naturally, is always bestowed withthe competition authority.In cases, where the competition authority also has adjudicative power, then itcan give out orders and decisions on cases based on their <strong>in</strong>vestigation andanalysis results. The competition law enforcement system, thus, is completedwith<strong>in</strong> one s<strong>in</strong>gle agency. For reasons of accountability though, such decisionsof the competition authority are usually subject to appeal, which can be takenup by the firms <strong>in</strong>volved at a court of higher authority with<strong>in</strong> the judiciarysystem of the country. In this model, private right of action is usually limited.The EU follows this system; with decisions and orders given out by the EuropeanCommission (EC) be<strong>in</strong>g subject to appeals.There are also other systems, where theadjudicative power is separated from the<strong>in</strong>vestigative arm, which is the competitionauthority. One of such systems is when thecompetition authority (be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> charge of<strong>in</strong>vestigat<strong>in</strong>g restrictive trade practices aswell as M&A cases) may br<strong>in</strong>g competitioncases before a court of law for adjudication.In the meanwhile, private parties also havea parallel right to br<strong>in</strong>g their own casedirectly before the court. This is the case <strong>in</strong>the US. In India too, such a power exists. Inaddition to this, consumers and theirorganisations too can br<strong>in</strong>g action. Thissystem helps to keep a check on the<strong>in</strong>vestigative and prosecutorial arm of theagency to be vigilant and active.88 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Alternatively, adjudication may be undertaken by a specialised competitiontribunal, which belongs to the overall judicial system of a country. This ismeant to take care of the dearth of special expertise amongst judges adjudicat<strong>in</strong>gall sorts of civil and crim<strong>in</strong>al matters at the same time. On the other hand, ithelps to avoid the problem of the all too great concentration of power <strong>in</strong> a fully<strong>in</strong>tegrated competition authority. One such model, which has proven to bevery successful so far, is that of South Africa, where the enforcement system isbifurcated between the <strong>Competition</strong> Commission and the <strong>Competition</strong> Tribunal.This is called a ‘self-conta<strong>in</strong>ed’ system and is strongly recommended <strong>in</strong> theOECD-World Bank Model <strong>Law</strong>.In the case of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, the <strong>in</strong>vestigative power rests solely with the <strong>Competition</strong>Adm<strong>in</strong>istration Department of the M<strong>in</strong>istry of Trade, which can also hands outorders and approvals <strong>in</strong> the case of unfair competition acts and M&As.Adjudication over restrictive bus<strong>in</strong>ess practices lies with an agency called the<strong>Competition</strong> Council. The Trade M<strong>in</strong>ister and the Prime M<strong>in</strong>ister authoriseexception and exemption cases. 89This separation of powers is expected to help to establish trust <strong>in</strong> the fairnessof competition law enforcement, especially <strong>in</strong> view that the competitionauthority is located with<strong>in</strong> the Trade M<strong>in</strong>istry. Establish<strong>in</strong>g a specialised bodyshould help develop knowledge and expertise and avoid the trouble of hav<strong>in</strong>gto go to the courts <strong>in</strong> every case, which is time and resource <strong>in</strong>tensive and somight limit the number of cases that a split-power competition structure is ableto handle. However, <strong>in</strong> practice, most members of the Council are high-levelpersonnel from relevant m<strong>in</strong>istries and regulatory bodies, appo<strong>in</strong>ted as ex officioofficials, rather than permanent full-time judges. Though this may help tofacilitate <strong>in</strong>ter-agency cooperation, it has the drawback of hav<strong>in</strong>g a low levelof professionalism and expertise, which defeat the orig<strong>in</strong>al objectives ofseparat<strong>in</strong>g powers and develop<strong>in</strong>g specialised expertise.ESSENTIAL ELEMENTS FOR SUCCESSAdvocacy power: An important set of powers for a develop<strong>in</strong>g countrycompetition authority is the power of advocacy. In order to create a competitionculture, awareness of competition issues and how they affect various groupsneeds to be created among bus<strong>in</strong>esses, consumers, policymakers and the media.This would help to <strong>in</strong>crease compliance and deterrent effects, foster recognitionand acceptance of competition mechanism with<strong>in</strong> the society, as well as generatesupport for competition law enforcement. The authority will need to allocateresources for these activities. Besides, <strong>in</strong> order to conduct these activitieseffectively, advocacy should be specifically <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the mandate of theauthority. In many countries <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g India, such a power is granted to thecompetition authority.In the case of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, the law does not mandate the competition authorityand adjudicative council to undertake any activities except enforcement, thoughthe <strong>Competition</strong> Adm<strong>in</strong>istration Department has tried to <strong>in</strong>tegrate a strongelement of advocacy <strong>in</strong> most of its activities so far. This lack of legal mandate,<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 89


ESSENTIAL ELEMENTS FOR SUCCESShowever, may straddle the agency’s budget. An alternative option is to generatesupport from <strong>in</strong>ternational fund<strong>in</strong>g agencies, or to enter <strong>in</strong>to partnership foradvocacy with some civil society organisations (CSOs) of high credibility.Legal enforcement tools: There are several legal provisions that affect the<strong>in</strong>stitutional competence of the competition authorities.To beg<strong>in</strong> with, the provisions of the law, especially those that determ<strong>in</strong>e the<strong>in</strong>stitutional structure and powers of the competition authority, should becompatible with general legal pr<strong>in</strong>ciples and constitutional values.Secondly, the <strong>in</strong>vestigative powers vested with the competition authority shouldbe broad. <strong>Competition</strong> authorities need to ably monitor markets and obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>formation on the conduct of market participants if they are to be effective.To perform such tasks, the authorities must be equipped with <strong>in</strong>vestigativetools that enable it to obta<strong>in</strong> the relevant <strong>in</strong>formation. For example, they shouldbe empowered to enter <strong>in</strong>to bus<strong>in</strong>ess premises to collect <strong>in</strong>formation, to<strong>in</strong>vestigate managers and employees of firms and to demand <strong>in</strong>formation frombus<strong>in</strong>ess entities, where there is suspicion of violation. There should also be ahigh penalty for fail<strong>in</strong>g to comply with <strong>in</strong>vestigative efforts.Last but not least, the authorities should be able to impose high penalties foranticompetitive conduct. The level of deterrence of a law is largely determ<strong>in</strong>edby the probability of detection of a violation and the height of sanction imposedupon the violator. If sanctions were not sufficiently high, then it would still berational for market players to engage <strong>in</strong> anticompetitive conduct, and thenwill<strong>in</strong>gly pay f<strong>in</strong>e if caught. This is particularly true <strong>in</strong> the case of largemult<strong>in</strong>ational companies, or serious violations where economic rents earnedare enormous. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, the law should provide the enforc<strong>in</strong>g bodies withsanctions that are high enough to act as a dis<strong>in</strong>centive to engage <strong>in</strong>anticompetitive conduct, when tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account enforcement levels.The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, fortunately, meets all these conditions. Thecompetition authority and adjudicative council have been established and willsoon be fully operational. They also have the powers to undertake premiseraids and <strong>in</strong>dividual searches, issue cautions and cease-and-desist orders. ‘Forbus<strong>in</strong>ess practices which violate the provisions on competition-restrict<strong>in</strong>gagreements, abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ant position on the market, abuse of monopolyposition or economic concentration, the relevant agencies may impose f<strong>in</strong>es ofup to 10 percent of total turnover earned by the violat<strong>in</strong>g organisations or<strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>in</strong> the fiscal year preced<strong>in</strong>g the year when they commit the violativeacts’. 9010.2.2. Independence from Political InterferenceAutonomy: <strong>Competition</strong> authorities may take one of a number of differentstructures. The most <strong>in</strong>dependent <strong>in</strong>stitutions are not only adm<strong>in</strong>istrativelyseparate from the government, but they are also staffed by competition90 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


professionals and do not rely on thegovernment for budget allocation. The least<strong>in</strong>dependent authorities are those that formpart of a government M<strong>in</strong>istry and are alsotherefore subject to civil service restrictionson recruitment and on central budgetallocations for the adm<strong>in</strong>istrative personnel.In some circumstances, however, thepoliticisation of the antitrust authority neednot be rejected. Russia provides a fasc<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g example. Russia has adopted anAntimonopoly <strong>Law</strong> as an <strong>in</strong>tegral part of wide-scale economic reforms to movefrom a centralised, communist government to a market-oriented economy. Inthe beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g, a m<strong>in</strong>ister, who is an active member of government, headed theRussian Antimonopoly M<strong>in</strong>istry. This proved to be beneficial: the antitrustpr<strong>in</strong>ciples were so different from the embedded ones that to be effective, thehead of the antitrust authority had to be a strong political figure that took part<strong>in</strong> the m<strong>in</strong>isterial discussions on the adoption of economic policy. Althoughsome decisions were based on political considerations, others could not havebeen reached or implemented without strong political power. Once the neweconomic order matures, however, it might be wise to change the <strong>in</strong>stitutionalorganisation and create a more autonomous agency. 91The Russian system was changed <strong>in</strong> 2004, when the authority was turned froma M<strong>in</strong>istry to a Federal Antimonopoly Service, after ga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g some experience.How, the head of the Korean Fair Trade Commission (KFTC) is also a memberof the m<strong>in</strong>isterial cab<strong>in</strong>et. Political <strong>in</strong>terference, therefore, clearly cannot bedeterm<strong>in</strong>ed by look<strong>in</strong>g only at the structure of the relevant <strong>in</strong>stitutions.www.google.comESSENTIAL ELEMENTS FOR SUCCESSThis is also the case <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>, where the lack of autonomy <strong>in</strong> the competitionauthority (which is placed <strong>in</strong> the M<strong>in</strong>istry of Trade, with the Trade M<strong>in</strong>isterhav<strong>in</strong>g a large power over it) has been an issue of much controversy. However,it is also recognised that the Trade M<strong>in</strong>istry is the only place where knowledgeand expertise on competition issues is available. Perhaps this should be theoptimal model at the moment and one should wait for a longer term for theauthority to evolve <strong>in</strong>to a completely <strong>in</strong>dependent body.Good leadership: Experience from many countries shows that the effectivenessof a competition authority fluctuates with the quality of the authority’sleadership. In reality, the head of the agency largely determ<strong>in</strong>es the authority’spriorities and the outcomes of its decisions. Even if (s)he is not legallyempowered to authorise certa<strong>in</strong> types of conduct, (s)he may nonetheless decidewhether or not to conduct an <strong>in</strong>quiry of certa<strong>in</strong> markets. It is thus crucial that(s)he not be politically oriented towards any specific group of <strong>in</strong>terests.Although political pressures on the nom<strong>in</strong>ation process cannot be totallyelim<strong>in</strong>ated, it is important to m<strong>in</strong>imise such pressures.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 91


ESSENTIAL ELEMENTS FOR SUCCESSBesides, as already touched upon <strong>in</strong> the examples of Russia and Korea above,it is extremely helpful if the leader of a new competition authority has personalprestige, as this will give the <strong>in</strong>stitution itself higher stand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the politicalarena and also <strong>in</strong> the eyes of the public. It is also helpful if the leader has goodpolitical contacts that can assist him <strong>in</strong> tak<strong>in</strong>g up more controversial cases.10.2.3. Political SupportPolitical support and deal<strong>in</strong>g with various <strong>in</strong>terest groups: As an extension ofthe po<strong>in</strong>t above, political support is crucial to the success of competition law.This will enable the passage of legislation and probably provide more<strong>in</strong>dependence and resources for the authority that will implement the policy.Wide publicity about the competition authority and its support from keypoliticians will make it more difficult for the politicians to backtrack on theircommitment under pressurefrom special <strong>in</strong>terest groups.Political back<strong>in</strong>g will raise theprofile of competition issuesand create public awarenessthrough the media.In the course of its work, thecompetition authority willhave to take on entrencheddomestic <strong>in</strong>terest groups. Many of these groups will have benefited fromprotection from competition <strong>in</strong> the past from domestic or foreign sources andcont<strong>in</strong>ue to be very <strong>in</strong>fluential <strong>in</strong> the political system. High-level politicalback<strong>in</strong>g will be necessary to ensure that there is no political <strong>in</strong>terference <strong>in</strong> thework of the competition authority and its decisions are carried out.www.google.comInterface with other regulators: <strong>Competition</strong> law is just one element ofcompetition policy. The effectiveness of the competition law will depend onthe extent to which it is coord<strong>in</strong>ated with other regulatory policies and,consequently, the most direct overlap will be with sectoral regulators govern<strong>in</strong>gkey utility sectors, which are mandated to create and promote competition <strong>in</strong>the regulated sector. The boundaries and roles of the sectoral regulators andthe competition authority are difficult to def<strong>in</strong>e and <strong>in</strong> many countries the overlapissues rema<strong>in</strong> unresolved. Ideally, the sectoral regulators would concentrateon the structure of the sector, try<strong>in</strong>g to create a competitive market so that theregulator’s day-to-day role <strong>in</strong> sett<strong>in</strong>g prices would dim<strong>in</strong>ish over time.The role of the competition authority would be to deal with cases of anticompetitivepractices when they arise. However, it is likely that sectoralregulators will cont<strong>in</strong>ue to play a hands-on role for the foreseeable future. Toprevent potential conflict and confusion, the competition law and the sectorallaws should specify clearly the circumstances under which the competitionauthority could <strong>in</strong>vestigate the behaviour of companies <strong>in</strong> the regulated sector.92 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


The legislation should also def<strong>in</strong>e a consultative role for the competitionauthority <strong>in</strong> the implementation and development of sector regulatory policies.In the case of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 specifies that ‘where thereis any disparity between the provisions of this <strong>Law</strong> and those of other lawsregard<strong>in</strong>g competition-restrict<strong>in</strong>g practices or unfair competition acts, theprovisions of this <strong>Law</strong> shall apply’. 92 This means the competition authoritywill have power over all behavioural competition issues <strong>in</strong> all sectors, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gregulated ones, while the sectoral regulatory bodies there<strong>in</strong> will look afterstructural as well as technical issues.Support of an active consumer movement: An active consumer movement hasbeen long recognised as mak<strong>in</strong>g a significant difference to the effectiveness ofcompetition law specifically and reforms generally. Empowered consumersand representative organisations will br<strong>in</strong>g anti-competition cases, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gabuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ance and collusion, to the attention of the competition authority.They will also act as a positive pressure to counteract the opposition of<strong>in</strong>efficient bus<strong>in</strong>esses to the successful implementation of the law.Many consumers are not aware of the relevance of competition law. Therefore,consumer organisations have an important role <strong>in</strong> demonstrat<strong>in</strong>g the importanceof competition law by connect<strong>in</strong>g the law with people’s everyday experiencesand products with which they are familiar.The only recognised consumer organisation <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong> to date is the <strong>Vietnam</strong>Standards and <strong>Consumer</strong>s Association (VINASTAS), which is headquartered<strong>in</strong> Hanoi with branch offices all over the country. It has been actively <strong>in</strong>volvedwith the adoption and implementation process of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004of <strong>Vietnam</strong>. The organisation, however, suffers from serious resource constra<strong>in</strong>tsas well as leadership crisis (s<strong>in</strong>ce the older generation will not be able to shoulderresponsibility any longer). Government, as well as public support to developthe same, therefore, is crucial.ESSENTIAL ELEMENTS FOR SUCCESS10.2.4. Availability of ResourcesIn order for the competition authorities to function effectively, they clearlyneed adequate resources. The level of f<strong>in</strong>ancial support available and the wayit is used is important, but equally important are human resources.Human resources: The best law cannot be applied without adequate humanresources, i.e. a staff of sufficient size with adequate technical competence.The last condition is especially important <strong>in</strong> the area of competition law, whichoften <strong>in</strong>volves a high-level economic analysis that complements a legal one <strong>in</strong>order to detect and to analyse the effects of bus<strong>in</strong>ess conduct.<strong>Competition</strong> authorities thus need to employ lawyers, economists and<strong>in</strong>vestigators familiar with competition issues. In addition, several attorneyswith litigation experience and a sound knowledge of adm<strong>in</strong>istrative law andcivil procedure should be hired. Particularly <strong>in</strong> its early years, the competition<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 93


ESSENTIAL ELEMENTS FOR SUCCESSagency might be required to conv<strong>in</strong>ce the courts that its cases are procedurallysound and have substantive merit.F<strong>in</strong>ancial resources: F<strong>in</strong>ancial resources are a necessary complement for humanresources. These expenses encompass the salaries of professional andadm<strong>in</strong>istrative staff and the creation of an <strong>in</strong>frastructure to support the work ofsuch staff.S<strong>in</strong>ce competition law cases often consume large sums <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestigation andtrial costs, it is also vital that enforcement decisions be taken on a rationalbasis and cases should only be tried where enforcement costs are lower thanthe harm prevented <strong>in</strong> the specific case or by the possible deterrence effectsthat would prevent similar cases. This is especially true for small economies,which naturally have lower enforcement budgets.94 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


11. THE DESIRED FRAMEWORKFOR VIETNAMThe purpose of a competition law is to ensure that competition prevails <strong>in</strong>the market. A competition law that is successful <strong>in</strong> do<strong>in</strong>g this is an effectivelaw. There have been cases where a competition law which is too rigid, such asthe Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act (MRTP Act) 1969 of India,it might have the effect of h<strong>in</strong>der<strong>in</strong>g the competitive process <strong>in</strong> the market byexcessive bureaucratic control. 93On the other hand, a competition law, which is too lax, might leave large firmsf<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g it easy to elim<strong>in</strong>ate other players from the market by restrictive practices,or exploit<strong>in</strong>g the consumer. Therefore, the competition law of a country has tostrike a proper balance between freedom to do bus<strong>in</strong>ess and regulation ofbus<strong>in</strong>ess activity. From the earlier discussion, some po<strong>in</strong>ts are summarisedbelow, which should be kept <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d while build<strong>in</strong>g the competition regime of<strong>Vietnam</strong>:11.1. Appropriate Revision of Certa<strong>in</strong> Provisions of the <strong>Law</strong>Certa<strong>in</strong> provision of the laws have the fault of be<strong>in</strong>g either too lax or too rigid,and need to be revised more appropriately, to match with the human andf<strong>in</strong>ancial resources available. This would help to save on enforcement costsfor such cases, which are over-burden<strong>in</strong>g for a young and resource-constra<strong>in</strong>edcompetition authority like that of <strong>Vietnam</strong>. The rule of reason applied for suchanticompetitive agreements <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>, for example, is too lax and mightimpose unnecessary enforcement burden. On theother hand, provisions which detail out the contentof an <strong>in</strong>vestigation and the steps to take (such asdef<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g relevant markets, calculat<strong>in</strong>g marketshares, etc – Art. 89(1) of the <strong>Law</strong>) <strong>in</strong> all casesmight be unnecessarily rigid.Certa<strong>in</strong> provision of thelaws have the fault ofbe<strong>in</strong>g either too lax ortoo rigid, and need to berevised moreappropriately.Most importantly, Article 8 and 13 appear torequire bus<strong>in</strong>esses to know their own marketshares before undertak<strong>in</strong>g certa<strong>in</strong> activities, whether <strong>in</strong> enter<strong>in</strong>g agreements or<strong>in</strong> merg<strong>in</strong>g with other enterprises, and therefore know whether they are coveredby the <strong>Law</strong> or not. This is virtually impossible and might underm<strong>in</strong>e thecredibility and workability of the <strong>Law</strong>, as discussed <strong>in</strong> earlier sections. It wouldbe preferable, given the desire to exempt small and medium-sized bus<strong>in</strong>esses,to determ<strong>in</strong>e coverage of the <strong>Law</strong> by def<strong>in</strong>ition of this term. Everyone elseought to be subject to the requirements of the <strong>Law</strong>. Figures on market sharewill still matter <strong>in</strong> terms of prov<strong>in</strong>g anticompetitive effects but at least bus<strong>in</strong>esseswill be on notice whether they are covered by the <strong>Law</strong> or not.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 95


THE DESIRED FRAMEWORK FOR VIETNAM11.2. Clear Differentiation between Horizontal and Vertical<strong>Competition</strong> Restra<strong>in</strong>tsThe provisions of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> address<strong>in</strong>ganticompetitive agreements do not entail a clear differentiation betweenhorizontal and vertical ones. Many of such provisions can be applied for bothcases. This should be rectified <strong>in</strong> the next amendment of the law, or theapplication of the law towards the two types of agreements should be clearlyexpla<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> some guidel<strong>in</strong>es for the public, with a view to avoid<strong>in</strong>g harshtreatment toward efficiency-enhanc<strong>in</strong>g vertical agreements or unnecessaryexemption for anticompetitive horizontal ones.11.3. Publication of Reader-friendly Implementation Guidel<strong>in</strong>esThe adoption of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>is a great step forward <strong>in</strong> promot<strong>in</strong>g competition <strong>in</strong> the<strong>Vietnam</strong> economy. Together with it, severalimplementation regulations were also issued such as theDecree 116/2005, whichexpla<strong>in</strong>s severalprovisions of thelaw, the Decree120/2005, which stipulates the variouslevels of f<strong>in</strong>e and remedies forcompetition violations, etc. However, allthese documents are highly technical andnot yet have much public ownership. Inthis regard, reader-friendly guidel<strong>in</strong>es onimportant features of the law, which hasgreat significance on advocacy, publicReader-friendlyguidel<strong>in</strong>es on importantfeatures of the law,which has greatsignificance onadvocacy, publiceducation as well ascompliance, should bepublished anddistributed widely.education as well as compliance, should be published and distributed widely.A live website should also be ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed to allow curious people to access<strong>in</strong>formation.11.4. More Comprehensive Coverage of the <strong>Law</strong>Several important issues have not been explicitly dealt with <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Competition</strong><strong>Law</strong> 2004 and should be <strong>in</strong>serted, such as refusal to deal, the <strong>in</strong>terface withsectoral regulators, issues related to IPRs, the knowledge economy, etc.One rather important anticompetitive practice that is not mentioned <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Law</strong>is refusal to deal, while this very practice is dealt with (though not substantially)<strong>in</strong> the sectoral regulation for telecommunications. On the other hand, thecompetition law is supposed to prevail over other laws and policies on allcompetition matters. While refusal to deal is a competition matter, one wouldnot know how to deal with this issue when there is conflict between the twolaws.96 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


11.5. Specific Regulation over IPRs-related <strong>Competition</strong> Issues<strong>Competition</strong> law and <strong>in</strong>tellectual property law, especially the enforcement ofthese laws, are quite new to <strong>Vietnam</strong>. Given the substantial <strong>in</strong>terface betweenthe two areas, if the <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese policymakers and enforcement authoritiescould determ<strong>in</strong>e a reasonable balance between them, it can help attract andencourage technology transfer, while at the same time promote the establishmentof a competitive bus<strong>in</strong>ess environment promot<strong>in</strong>g both customer welfare andsocial benefits. While the IPRs <strong>Law</strong> 2005 of <strong>Vietnam</strong> has touched upon thissubject, and refer all IPRs-related competition matters to the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>2004 of the country, the latter has been unable to deal with the same <strong>in</strong> anexhaustive and appropriate manner.11.6. Extension of Jurisdiction beyond Territorial BoundariesIn the era of globalisation, a competition law which lacks jurisdiction to tryany anticompetitive practices orig<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g from outside its country (thoughhav<strong>in</strong>g substantial adverse effects on the competitive process <strong>in</strong> its domesticmarket) would only be half-effective. The <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>,therefore, <strong>in</strong> its next amendment, should widen the scope of regulation to suchpractices to avoid this surmountable hurdle. Besides, other issues with foreignelements, hav<strong>in</strong>g substantial impact on trade and livelihood <strong>in</strong> the country,such as export and import cartels, compulsory licens<strong>in</strong>g of IPRs on grounds ofpublic <strong>in</strong>terest should also be dealt with.11.7. Build<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Competition</strong> Authorities’ Human ResourcesThe <strong>Competition</strong> Council, the adjudicative agency on competition matters <strong>in</strong><strong>Vietnam</strong>, as said, might be staffed with bureaucrats from various relevantm<strong>in</strong>istries and regulatory agencies. Appo<strong>in</strong>tment of <strong>in</strong>dependent judges (atleast as a majority of the council, <strong>in</strong> addition to some key figures <strong>in</strong> thegovernment) should be a more viable option. Besides, for all members of theCouncil, their judicial competence should be built up; similarly as the<strong>in</strong>vestigative skills of the competition authority should be constantly enhanced.THE DESIRED FRAMEWORK FOR VIETNAMConsider<strong>in</strong>g the serious shortage of personnel with competence and specialisedqualification <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, the competition authorities should deviseways to overcome such obstacles. In the long run, low levels of professionalismcan be countered by build<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>in</strong>ks with universities. In the short run, stafftra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g programmes <strong>in</strong> procedural, methodological and substantive mattersshould be considered a top most priority. Such tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g can be provided<strong>in</strong>ternally, but often there is an important role for external tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g. Internships,or seconded staff from more mature authorities should be arranged to guidestaff while ga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g practical experience.11.8. Independence/Autonomy of the <strong>Competition</strong> AuthorityThe <strong>in</strong>dependence of the competition authority, as discussed <strong>in</strong> the preced<strong>in</strong>gsection, has a significant impact on the effectiveness of the overall competitionregime <strong>in</strong> any country. For the time be<strong>in</strong>g, maybe a less <strong>in</strong>dependent structure<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 97


THE DESIRED FRAMEWORK FOR VIETNAMis more suited for <strong>Vietnam</strong>. However, <strong>in</strong> the future, such structure should begradually changed and the authority should become fully <strong>in</strong>dependent.11.9. Active Involvement of <strong>Consumer</strong> and other CSOsThere is a need for the competition authority to engage consumer groups andother civil society organisations <strong>in</strong> educat<strong>in</strong>g and help<strong>in</strong>g the common man oncompetition issues, due to the latter’s credibility and neutrality.The consumer movement <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>, as said, is still at anascent stage, while most exist<strong>in</strong>g CSOs are either researchoriented(without a strong advocacy mandate) or partlypoliticised. The <strong>in</strong>dividual consumer’s awareness oncompetition issues is low, and so is their access to law andjustice. The competition authority of <strong>Vietnam</strong> shouldconstantly search for such CSOs or consumer organisationswith the same goals, extend support to them and make themstrong allies <strong>in</strong> build<strong>in</strong>g up a healthy competition culture <strong>in</strong><strong>Vietnam</strong>.98 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


ENDNOTES1 From Wikipedia, the free encyclopaedia, at ,as on April 03, 2007.2 For the purpose of simple explanation, only two actors of the market are consideredhere, which are buyers and sellers, or producers and consumers, presumably <strong>in</strong> as<strong>in</strong>gle sector. The role of the government will be discussed later, as well as anyother factors and actors.3 Y<strong>in</strong>gyi Qian (2000), The Modern Market Economy and the Rule of <strong>Law</strong>, availableat http://www.oycf.org/Perspectives/5_043000/modern_market_economy_and_the_ru.htm4 This is exclud<strong>in</strong>g the case where producers might have opportunistic, rent-seek<strong>in</strong>gor strategic behaviours; which would be discussed <strong>in</strong> subsequent sections. Forpurpose of simplicity, from here onwards, competition would be largely expla<strong>in</strong>ed<strong>in</strong> terms of prices.5 Reckon LLP, Glossary, at , as on April03, 2007.6 Web-based def<strong>in</strong>ition from 7 Rai, Qureshi & Saroliya (2003), Restrictive and Unfair Trade Practices – WhereStands the <strong>Consumer</strong>?, CUTS, India, p.5.8 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, Article 3(1).9 Article 4(5) of the Decree says “Goods or services shall be deemed capable ofbe<strong>in</strong>g substituted for each other <strong>in</strong> terms of price if above 50 percent of a randomsample quantity taken from 1,000 consumers liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the relevant geographicalarea change to purchas<strong>in</strong>g or <strong>in</strong>tend to purchase other goods or services with thesame characteristics and use purpose as the goods they are currently us<strong>in</strong>g or<strong>in</strong>tend to use where the price of such goods or services <strong>in</strong>creases more than 10%and rema<strong>in</strong>s stable for six consecutive months.Where the number of consumers liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the relevant geographical area stipulated<strong>in</strong> this clause is less than 1000, the m<strong>in</strong>imum random sample quantity shallbe equal to fifty (50) percent of the total number of such consumers.”10 Based on Office of Fair Trad<strong>in</strong>g (2004), Market <strong>Competition</strong> – Understand<strong>in</strong>g<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> (<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004), UK, p.20.11 Supra note 1, at as on April 03, 2007.12 Supra note 8, Article 3(5).13 Dennis Carlton & Jeffrey Perloff (2005), Modern <strong>in</strong>dustrial organisation, 4thEdition, The Addison – Weasley Series <strong>in</strong> Economics, p. 57.14 , as on April 03, 2007.15 The word is derived from the Greek language for few sellers.16 Addison Wesley, Student Resources – Glossary, at as on April 03, 2007.17 The discussion <strong>in</strong> this section draws from CUTS (2006), Promot<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Competition</strong>Policy and <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> Lao PDR – A Civil Society Perspective, p.1-2.18 For further discussion on this, see, for example, Kenneth Davidson (2005), Creat<strong>in</strong>gEffective <strong>Competition</strong> Institutions: Ideas for Transitional Economies, Asian &Pacific <strong>Law</strong> & Policy Journal, Volume 6, Issue 1 (W<strong>in</strong>ter 2005).19 ADB (2005), Asian Development Outlook 2005, Chapter III: Promot<strong>in</strong>g competitionfor long-term development, Asian Development Bank, at 20 Supra note 8, Article 3(3).<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 99


ENDNOTES21 OECD Glossary of Statistical Terms, at 22 The discussion <strong>in</strong> this section draws from Fruitman (2006), Abuse of Dom<strong>in</strong>ance<strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Economies – A Focus on the Issue <strong>in</strong> Cambodia, Laos and <strong>Vietnam</strong>,CUTS, p.10.23 Supra note 8, Article 11.24 Ibid., Article 12.25 Decree 116/2005, Article 22.26 Supra note 1, at as on April 03, 200727 Supra note 8, Article 10(1).28 Supra note 6, Article 9(2).29 Supra note 7, p. 16.30 Decree 116/2005, Article 14.31 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, Chapter II, Article 8 (1).32 CUTS (2001), <strong>Competition</strong> Policy and <strong>Law</strong> Made Easy, p.8.33 An <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g th<strong>in</strong>g about the absence of a need to show a 30 percent marketshare under Article 8 of the <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese <strong>Law</strong> is that if all the bidders collude, theircomb<strong>in</strong>ed market share for purposes of the bid is 100 percent. But go<strong>in</strong>g by theletters of the <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> 2004 of <strong>Vietnam</strong>, it would also be unlawful if onlysome bidders colluded and someone else submitted a lower bid and got the contract.34 Supra note 7, p.18.35 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>Gram (3/2006), Construct<strong>in</strong>g the Olympics: Why Collud<strong>in</strong>gfor Contracts May Land You <strong>in</strong> Jail, <strong>Law</strong>rence Graham LLP, London, Vol I,p.2, available for further read<strong>in</strong>g at 36 Supra note 8, Article 89.37 Khemani, R. Shyam, A Framework for the Design Implementation of <strong>Competition</strong><strong>Law</strong> and Policy, World Bank and OECD, p.20, as cited <strong>in</strong> Rai, Qureshi & Saroliya(2003), Restrictive and Unfair Trade Practices – Where Stands the <strong>Consumer</strong>?,CUTS, India.38 For further read<strong>in</strong>g, see Verouden (2005), Vertical Agreements: Motivation andImpacts, forthcom<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Directions <strong>in</strong> <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> and Policy, (W.D. Coll<strong>in</strong>s,ed.), American Bar Association, 2006, available at 39 Dobson & Waterson (1996), Vertical Restra<strong>in</strong>ts and <strong>Competition</strong> Policy, Officeof Fair Trad<strong>in</strong>g Research Paper 12, v-vi.40 Ibid.41 For further read<strong>in</strong>g, see OECD (1997), Resale Price Ma<strong>in</strong>tenance, Paris, OCDE/GD(97)229.42 Supra note 8, Article 9(2).43 Asker J. (2004), Measur<strong>in</strong>g Cost Advantages from Exclusive Deal<strong>in</strong>g – AnEmpirical Study of Beer Distribution, Harvard University, p.2.44 Ibid.45 See Cont<strong>in</strong>ental T.V. Inc. vs GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 US 36 (1977)46 See United States vs Microsoft, 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001).47 Supra note 8, Article 8(5).48 Supra note 8, Article 2(1).49 For further read<strong>in</strong>g, see DiLorenzo (1992), The Myth of Predatory Pric<strong>in</strong>g, CatoPolicy Analysis No. 169, or 100 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


50 An essential facility may be def<strong>in</strong>ed as a facility or <strong>in</strong>frastructure, without accessto which competitors cannot provide services to their customers. An essentialfacility may exist either at the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g (upstream) or distribution(downstream) level. Examples of essential facilities <strong>in</strong>clude technical <strong>in</strong>formation,transport <strong>in</strong>frastructure (e.g., rail, port or airport) and pipel<strong>in</strong>es/wire for the supplyof water, gas, electricity or telecommunications services.51 The <strong>Law</strong> does not mention this <strong>in</strong> a clear manner, but it is possible, as provided byArticle 86 of the <strong>Law</strong>, which says “the decision of <strong>in</strong>itiat<strong>in</strong>g a prelim<strong>in</strong>ary<strong>in</strong>vestigation shall be made either by (i) competition case dossiers/compla<strong>in</strong>tsaccepted by the authority, or (ii) the competition authority detects signs of violationof the <strong>Law</strong>”.52 John R. Davis, The Structure of Discretion <strong>in</strong> ASEAN <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>s,Presentation at the <strong>Competition</strong> Policy Conference on Challenges <strong>in</strong> <strong>Competition</strong><strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> Asia, May, 2007 <strong>in</strong> Jakarta, available at as of June 2007.53 The discussion <strong>in</strong> this section draws from International <strong>Competition</strong> Network(2006), Anti-Cartel Enforcement Manual (Chapter 2 – Draft<strong>in</strong>g and Implement<strong>in</strong>gan Effective Leniency Programme), Cartel Work<strong>in</strong>g Group – Subgroup 2:Enforcement Techniques.54 Based on def<strong>in</strong>itions from Wikipedia, the free encyclopaedia, at as on April 05, 2007.55 Ibid.56 Supra note 8, Article 17.57 Supra note 8, Article 18-19.58 The discussion <strong>in</strong> this section draw from Wash<strong>in</strong>gton State University,NetTel@Africa Off-L<strong>in</strong>e Content (2004), Mergers, Acquisitions and OtherCorporate Comb<strong>in</strong>ations, ICT Industry and Markets, p.53 of 73, available at 59 Ibid.60 Supra note 8, Article 20.61 Supra note 8, Article 18-19.62 Supra note 8, Article 117(3b).63 The discussion <strong>in</strong> this section draws from CUTS (2006), Fairplay Please!, p.112-113.64 Unfair trade practices <strong>in</strong> these contexts should be differentiated from unfair practices<strong>in</strong> the context of <strong>in</strong>ternational trade, which are usually related to dump<strong>in</strong>g andsubsidies.65 Supra note 7, p.32.66 Supra note 8, Article 3(4).67 Supra note 8, Article 39.68 Jamaica Fair Trad<strong>in</strong>g Commission, The FCA Prohibitions, at 69 See http://vnexpress.net/<strong>Vietnam</strong>/K<strong>in</strong>h-doanh/2005/01/3B9DADF3/ for moredetails.70 Multi-level market<strong>in</strong>g (MLM), also called network market<strong>in</strong>g or NM, is a bus<strong>in</strong>essmodel that comb<strong>in</strong>es direct market<strong>in</strong>g with franchis<strong>in</strong>g. In a typical MLMarrangement, <strong>in</strong>dividuals associate with a parent company as an <strong>in</strong>dependentcontractor and are compensated based on their sales of products or service, aswell as the sales achieved by those they br<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to the bus<strong>in</strong>ess. In a legitimateMLM company, commissions are earned only on sales of the company’s products.No money may be earned from recruit<strong>in</strong>g alone (“sign-up fees”). Some lesslegitimate companies produce revenues primarily by attract<strong>in</strong>g new participantsor sell<strong>in</strong>g them market<strong>in</strong>g services, as opposed to sell<strong>in</strong>g actual products. OneENDNOTES<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 101


ENDNOTESmust analyse the compensation plan to determ<strong>in</strong>e whether participants are paidfrom actual sales to customers and not from new-recruit bonuses or bus<strong>in</strong>ess supportsales.71 The discussion <strong>in</strong> this section draws from Mehta, Nanda & Pham (2005),Multilateral <strong>Competition</strong> Framework: In Need of a Fresh Approach, CUTS, India.72 This categorisation is borrowed from “Special Study on Trade and <strong>Competition</strong>Policy” as <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> Chapter Four of WTO Annual Report for 1997.73 It is important to note a particular case of (<strong>in</strong>ternational) export cartel, which isnot <strong>in</strong>cluded for discussion hereby, despite their makeup – the Organisation ofPetroleum Export<strong>in</strong>g Countries (OPEC). The oil cartel is supposedly outside therealm of antitrust action, as it is a sovereign activity of governments.74 Mehta (1999), Foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestment, mega-mergers and strategic alliances:Is global competition accelerat<strong>in</strong>g development or head<strong>in</strong>g towards worldmonopolies?. UNCTAD, The Role of <strong>Competition</strong> Policy for Development <strong>in</strong>Globalis<strong>in</strong>g World Markets, UNCTAD Series on Issues <strong>in</strong> <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> andPolicy, Geneva, United Nations.75 A section of the MRTP Act requir<strong>in</strong>g government approval for acquisition ortransfer of shares <strong>in</strong> excess of 25 percent of a firm’s equity was simultaneouslymoved to the Companies Act and made applicable only to acquisition by“dom<strong>in</strong>ant” firms as def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the MRTP Act (those with a market share of onefourthor more). This, however, does not apply to mergers and acquisitions.76 Nagesh Kumar (2000). Mult<strong>in</strong>ational enterprises and M&As <strong>in</strong> India: patternand implications. Paper presented at the UNCTAD Sem<strong>in</strong>ar on Cross-border M&Asand Susta<strong>in</strong>ed Competitiveness <strong>in</strong> Asia: Trends, Impacts and Policy Implications(Bangkok), mimeo.77 Supra note 8, Article 10(1c).78 Supra note 8, Article 19(2).79 Supra note 8, Article 40, 41 & 199.80 IPRs <strong>Law</strong> 2005, Article 7(2).81 The VCC 1995 was later replaced by a new Civil Code, promulgated by the NationalAssembly of <strong>Vietnam</strong> on June 14, 2005.82 IPRs <strong>Law</strong> 2005, Article 143(1).83 Cont<strong>in</strong>ental Paper Bag Co. v. Eastern Paper Bag Co., 210 U.S. 405, 429 (1908)84 IPRs <strong>Law</strong> 2005, Article 145(1c-d).85 This section is drawn from Pradeep S. Mehta (2003), Friends of <strong>Competition</strong> –How to Build an Effective <strong>Competition</strong> Regime <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g and TransitionEconomies, CUTS, India.86 Khemani, R. Shyam & M.A. Dutz, (196), The Instruments of <strong>Competition</strong> Policy& Their Relevance for Economic Development, PSD Occassional Paper No. 26(Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, World Bank).87 Russell Damtoft, Federal Trade Commission, US <strong>in</strong> a personal communication toPradeep S Mehta, Secretary General, CUTS.88 CUTS (2003), Towards a Healthy <strong>Competition</strong> Culture, pp.4089 Supra note 8, Article 49-55.90 Supra note 8, Article 118(1).91 Michal Gal (2004), The Ecology of Antitrust Preconditions for <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong>Enforcement <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries, New York University <strong>Law</strong> and EconomicsWork<strong>in</strong>g Paper No. 10/2004, Berkeley Electronic Press 92 Supra note 8, Article 5(1).93 Rai, Qureshi & Saroliya (2003), Restrictive and Unfair Trade Practices – WhereStands the <strong>Consumer</strong>?, CUTS, pp.37.102 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


GLOSSARYAAbuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ant position refers to the use of anticompetitive bus<strong>in</strong>esspractices by a dom<strong>in</strong>ant firm <strong>in</strong> order to restrict competition and hence ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>or <strong>in</strong>crease its position <strong>in</strong> the market.Acquisition of enterprises means an act whereby an enterprise acquires thewhole or part of property of another enterprise, which is sufficient to controlor dom<strong>in</strong>ate all or one of the trades of the acquired enterprise. In an acquisition,a company can buy another company with cash, stock or a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of thetwo. Another possibility, which is common <strong>in</strong> smaller deals, is for one companyto acquire all the assets of another company.Anticompetitive agreements are those agreements either between competitors(firms <strong>in</strong> a horizontal relationship) or those at different stages of productionand distribution cha<strong>in</strong> (firms <strong>in</strong> a vertical relationship) concern<strong>in</strong>g price,customer allocation, etc. These agreements help member firms to exercisecollective market power, restrict competition <strong>in</strong> order to seek unjust economicrents for all members.BBarriers to entry are factors which prevent or deter the entry of new firms <strong>in</strong>toan <strong>in</strong>dustry or a market even when <strong>in</strong>cumbent firms there<strong>in</strong> are earn<strong>in</strong>g excessprofits. There are two broad classes of barriers: structural (also called‘economic’) and behavioural (also called ‘strategic’). It should also be notedthat governments can be a source of entry barriers through licens<strong>in</strong>g and otherregulations (legal or adm<strong>in</strong>istrative).Bid rigg<strong>in</strong>g usually refers to the collaboration of competitors to restrictcompetition <strong>in</strong> response to a tender issued either by a public authority or by aprivate entity. It is universally viewed as one of the worst ‘hard-core’ carteltypeoffences along side price-fix<strong>in</strong>g, output restriction and market allocation,and is often a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of these practices.CCartels are arrangements between groups of firms that produce and sell thesame product for the purpose of exact<strong>in</strong>g and shar<strong>in</strong>g monopolistic rents. Mostcommonly, they accomplish this by agree<strong>in</strong>g on a relatively high common ask<strong>in</strong>gprice for their product that none of the member firms will be permitted tounderbid (i.e. price-fix<strong>in</strong>g cartels). Alternatively, the member firms may simplyagree to divide the market by geographic territory or by customers and granteach other local monopolies without necessarily enforc<strong>in</strong>g a uniform pricestructure (i.e. market allocat<strong>in</strong>g or customer shar<strong>in</strong>g cartels).<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 103


GLOSSARY OF TERMS USED IN TOOLKITCollusive tender<strong>in</strong>g: See Bid-rigg<strong>in</strong>g.<strong>Competition</strong> law is a body of legal rules and provisions that ensures fairnessand freedom <strong>in</strong> the marketplace by regulat<strong>in</strong>g the conducts of firms, prohibit<strong>in</strong>ganticompetitive arrangements and abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ance, which impede thecompetitive process and hamper the legitimate rights and <strong>in</strong>terests of othermarket players, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g consumers.<strong>Competition</strong> policy refers to those government measures that directly affectthe behaviour of firms and the structure of the <strong>in</strong>dustry. It is an <strong>in</strong>tegral part ofeconomic policy, and may embrace several elements such as trade liberalisation,<strong>in</strong>dustrial, <strong>in</strong>vestment, and privatisation policies, which have the ma<strong>in</strong> objectiveof preserv<strong>in</strong>g and promot<strong>in</strong>g competition as a means to ensure efficientallocation of resources <strong>in</strong> an economy, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the best possible choice ofquality, the lowest prices, and adequate supplies to consumers.Compulsory licens<strong>in</strong>g refers to the act by the state to impose an <strong>in</strong>voluntarycontract between a will<strong>in</strong>g buyer and an unwill<strong>in</strong>g seller. The three mostprevalent compulsory licens<strong>in</strong>g provisions are applicable where a dependentpatent is be<strong>in</strong>g blocked, where a patent is not be<strong>in</strong>g worked, or where an<strong>in</strong>vention relates to food or medic<strong>in</strong>e. Additionally, compulsory licens<strong>in</strong>g maybe implemented as a remedy <strong>in</strong> antitrust or misuse situations, where the<strong>in</strong>vention is important to national defence or where the entity acquir<strong>in</strong>g thecompulsory license is the sovereign. See also Licens<strong>in</strong>g agreements.<strong>Consumer</strong> protection policy is a body of legal rules enforced to ensure thatconsumers can make well-<strong>in</strong>formed decisions about their choices and that sellerswill fulfill their promises about the products they offer. In other words, consumerprotection policy prevents producers from engag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> unfair practices whileseek<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>crease their sales.Concentration of economic power is the action <strong>in</strong> which a firm aims to governother competitors, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g but not limited to mergers, acquisitions, jo<strong>in</strong>tventures and consolidations.Conditional approval is regulation or modification of the behaviour of mergedfirms <strong>in</strong> order to prevent or reduce anticompetitive effects which might likelyarise from some specific mergers. This can be achieved through a variety ofone-time conditions and on-go<strong>in</strong>g requirements.DDawn raids are those surprise <strong>in</strong>spections carried out by officials of competitionauthorities at the premises of the bus<strong>in</strong>ess or bus<strong>in</strong>esses suspected, to obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>crim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g evidence.Dissolution is the action of competition authorities to re-divide a merger whichhas already been consummated because of its anticompetitive effects and/orfailure (of the merg<strong>in</strong>g parties) to notify and obta<strong>in</strong> the approval of thecompetition authorities prior to the merger.Divestiture (also called ‘partial divestiture’) refers to the situation when amerged firm is required to divest part or whole of their assets or operations to104 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


elim<strong>in</strong>ate identified anti-competitive effects, with permission to proceed withthe merger <strong>in</strong> other respect.EExclusive deal<strong>in</strong>g is a vertical agreement by which a retailer or wholesaler is‘tied’ to purchase from a supplier on the understand<strong>in</strong>g that no other distributorwill be appo<strong>in</strong>ted or receive supplies <strong>in</strong> a given area.Export cartels are agreements or arrangements between firms to charge aspecified export price and/or to divide export markets. Such agreements areusually exempted from the scrut<strong>in</strong>y of many countries’ competition statutes,unless when they lead to <strong>in</strong>jurious effects on competition <strong>in</strong> the domestic market,e.g., give rise to price fix<strong>in</strong>g agreements or result <strong>in</strong> reduction <strong>in</strong> exports.Extra-territorial jurisdiction is the power conferred upon competitionauthorities by their countries’ competition law statutes to try anticompetitivepractices orig<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g from outside their countries’ territory but hav<strong>in</strong>gsubstantial adverse effects on the competitive process <strong>in</strong> their domestic markets.GGeographic market (also called ‘geographic relevant market’) is the relevantmarket <strong>in</strong> competition case analyses def<strong>in</strong>ed by the ability of customers orconsumers to switch purchase between suppliers of substitute products <strong>in</strong> caseof a price hike.GLOSSARY OF TERMS USED IN TOOLKITHHorizontal anticompetitive agreements: See Cartels.IImport cartels are agreements between domestic importers <strong>in</strong> order to ga<strong>in</strong>control over some specific import markets and to act as a counterbalance aga<strong>in</strong>stexport cartels. See also Export cartels.JJo<strong>in</strong>t refusal to deal (also called ‘boycott’) is a jo<strong>in</strong>t action by competitorsthat has the purpose of us<strong>in</strong>g the comb<strong>in</strong>ed market power of those competitorsto force a supplier, a competitor or a customer to agree to an action that harmscompetition, which would not be agreed to, absent the jo<strong>in</strong>t action. See alsoRefusal to deal.Jo<strong>in</strong>t venture is an association of firms or <strong>in</strong>dividuals established to undertakea specific bus<strong>in</strong>ess project. Jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures should be scrut<strong>in</strong>ised by competitionauthorities when they are formed by compet<strong>in</strong>g firms <strong>in</strong> a relevant market.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 105


GLOSSARY OF TERMS USED IN TOOLKITLLeniency is a generic term used to describe a system of partial or total amnestyfrom the penalties that would otherwise be applicable to a cartel member,which reports its cartel membership to a competition authority. In addition,competition authority decisions that could be considered lenient treatment<strong>in</strong>clude agree<strong>in</strong>g to pursue a reduction <strong>in</strong> penalties or not to refer a matter forcrim<strong>in</strong>al prosecution. The term leniency, thus, could be used to refer to totalimmunity and “lenient treatment”, which means less than full immunity.Licens<strong>in</strong>g agreements are arrangements by which a firm or a person confersthe right to do someth<strong>in</strong>g, such as to use a patent, or produce a product, onanother firm or person, which the latter earlier did not possess. Licens<strong>in</strong>gagreements may conta<strong>in</strong> restrictions as to how the license is employed, whichmight affect the competitive process <strong>in</strong> the relevant markets adversely.MMarket power refers to the ability of an <strong>in</strong>dividual firm or a group of firms toraise and ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> price above the level which would prevail under competition.The highest degree of market power is associated with a monopoly, althoughall firms; except for those operat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> perfectly competitive markets; possesssome degree of market power.Market share, <strong>in</strong> strategic management and market<strong>in</strong>g, is the percentage orproportion of the total available market or market segment that is be<strong>in</strong>g servicedby a company. In the competition world, market share of a company will varyaccord<strong>in</strong>g to the def<strong>in</strong>ition of relevant markets. The smaller the relevant marketdef<strong>in</strong>ed for a particular case, the higher share a company may account for <strong>in</strong>that market.Market allocat<strong>in</strong>g (or ‘customer shar<strong>in</strong>g’) refers to cartel agreements thatdivide markets by territory or by customers among competitors.Merger is an amalgamation or jo<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g of two firms or more <strong>in</strong> which one orseveral firms transfer all of its/their property, rights, obligations and legitimate<strong>in</strong>terests <strong>in</strong>to an exist<strong>in</strong>g firm or to form a new firm. Mergers can becharacterised accord<strong>in</strong>g to three categories: horizontal mergers, which takeplace between firms that are actual or potential competitors occupy<strong>in</strong>g similarpositions <strong>in</strong> the cha<strong>in</strong> of production; vertical mergers, which take place betweenfirms at different levels <strong>in</strong> the cha<strong>in</strong> of production (such as betweenmanufacturers and retailers); and other mergers, such as those which take placebetween companies that sell the same products <strong>in</strong> different markets (marketextensionmergers), or companies sell<strong>in</strong>g different but related products <strong>in</strong> thesame market (product-extension mergers), or conglomerates with different typesof bus<strong>in</strong>esses.Merger review is the process of evaluat<strong>in</strong>g a merger’s current conditions aswell as its potential impacts over the competitive process <strong>in</strong> relevant marketsby competition authorities <strong>in</strong> order to decide whether to prohibit or to approvethem (wholly or with conditions).106 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Mislead<strong>in</strong>g advertis<strong>in</strong>g refers to any false or unfounded representation relatedto products made to the public by a company. The representation may beabout the nature, character or performance of a product, such as size, type ofcontents or weight. It also <strong>in</strong>cludes warranties, statements, or guarantees thatare not based on adequate and proper tests.Monopoly is a market structure characterised by a s<strong>in</strong>gle firm sell<strong>in</strong>g a productfor which there are no close substitutes and by substantial barriers to entry”.NNormal competition is a market structure <strong>in</strong> which a large number of firmscompete with each other by mak<strong>in</strong>g similar but slightly different products.Each of the firm has some control over the prices it charges s<strong>in</strong>ce products aredifferentiated. However, s<strong>in</strong>ce there are no significant barriers to entry andproducts are closely substitutable, the firm cannot affect the market as a whole.OOligopoly a market structure <strong>in</strong> which the market is dom<strong>in</strong>ated by a smallnumber of sellers or buyers (‘oligopolists’). Because there are few participants<strong>in</strong> this type of market, each oligopolist is aware that it can affect market priceand hence its competitors’ profits. Oligopolistic markets, thus, can be said asbe<strong>in</strong>g characterised by <strong>in</strong>ter-relationship between market participants. A firmmust consider rival firms’ behaviours to determ<strong>in</strong>e its own best policy.Output restriction happens when enterprises produc<strong>in</strong>g/supply<strong>in</strong>g the sameproducts/services agree to limit their supplies to a lower proportion of theirprevious sales. The effect of limit<strong>in</strong>g supplies is to create scarcity <strong>in</strong> the market,which makes it possible for sellers to raise prices of products/services.GLOSSARY OF TERMS USED IN TOOLKITPParallel imports are goods brought <strong>in</strong>to a country without the authorisation ofthe patent, trademark or copyright holders after those goods were placedlegitimately <strong>in</strong>to the market elsewhere. Unlike pirated copyright goods orcounterfeit trademark goods, parallel imports are legitimate products, as arguedby some, s<strong>in</strong>ce the holders of the IPRs <strong>in</strong> question have agreed to put them<strong>in</strong>to market and thus implicitly authorised their subsequent use, be it be<strong>in</strong>gimported by an unauthorised distributor.Perfect competition is an ideal market structure <strong>in</strong> which all firms produce ahomogeneous, perfectly divisible output; producers and consumers have full<strong>in</strong>formation, <strong>in</strong>cur transaction costs and are price takers; and there are noexternalities. S<strong>in</strong>ce perfect competition is rarely, if ever, encountered <strong>in</strong> thereal world, it is mentioned here only as an ideal aga<strong>in</strong>st which to compareother types of market structures.Per se rule is a regulatory approach by which some certa<strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess practicesare conclusively presumed to impose unreasonable restra<strong>in</strong>t on the competitive<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 107


GLOSSARY OF TERMS USED IN TOOLKITprocess and thus anticompetitive, or can be held as illegal by themselves,without further defence. See also Rule of Reason.Predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g occurs when a dom<strong>in</strong>ant firm temporarily chargesparticularly low prices <strong>in</strong> an attempt to elim<strong>in</strong>ate exist<strong>in</strong>g competitors, or createa barrier to entry <strong>in</strong>to the market for potential new competitors. The predatorwill <strong>in</strong>cur temporary losses dur<strong>in</strong>g its low pric<strong>in</strong>g policy with the <strong>in</strong>tention ofrais<strong>in</strong>g prices <strong>in</strong> the future to recoup losses and ga<strong>in</strong> further profits.Price discrim<strong>in</strong>ation is the practice of apply<strong>in</strong>g different conditions, normallydifferent prices for the same products to different customers.Price fix<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>cludes a wide variety of concerted actions undertaken bycompetitors which have a direct effect on pricePrivate <strong>in</strong>ternational cartels are conspiracies <strong>in</strong> restra<strong>in</strong>t of trade (whether byfix<strong>in</strong>g prices, allocat<strong>in</strong>g markets or customers, or rigg<strong>in</strong>g tenders, etc) thathave or allegedly have one or more corporate or <strong>in</strong>dividual participants withheadquarters, residency or nationality outside the jurisdiction of the<strong>in</strong>vestigat<strong>in</strong>g competition authorities.Product market (also called ‘product relevant market’) is a market that <strong>in</strong>cludesall products that are close substitutes for one another, both <strong>in</strong> consumptionand <strong>in</strong> production.Pyramid sell<strong>in</strong>g is a non-susta<strong>in</strong>able bus<strong>in</strong>ess model that <strong>in</strong>volves the exchangeof money primarily for enroll<strong>in</strong>g other people <strong>in</strong>to the scheme, usually withoutany product or service really be<strong>in</strong>g delivered.RRefusal to deal is the situation when a seller refuses to deal with a purchaser,usually when the purchaser has limited options of alternative supply. Thecompetitive effects of refusal to deal have to be weighed on a cases-to-casebasis. See also Jo<strong>in</strong>t refusal to deal.Relevant market is the concept used <strong>in</strong> competition case analyses which def<strong>in</strong>esthe extent of effective constra<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> the market <strong>in</strong> terms of product/services,time and location. See also Product market and Geographic market.Remedies refer to those undertak<strong>in</strong>gs imposed and enforced by competitionauthorities <strong>in</strong> order to remove the adverse effects on competition and consumerscaused by certa<strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess practices or arrangements, or to prevent suchconsequences <strong>in</strong> the future.Resale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenance is the practice whereby a manufacturer and itsdistributors agree that the latter will sell products of the former at certa<strong>in</strong> prices(resale price ma<strong>in</strong>tenance), at or above a price floor (m<strong>in</strong>imum resale pricema<strong>in</strong>tenance) or at or below a price ceil<strong>in</strong>g (maximum resale pricema<strong>in</strong>tenance).Restriction on end-users refer to those restrictive requirements by a holder of<strong>in</strong>tellectual property rights that exclude end-users from the benefits ofcompetition, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g but not limited to technological <strong>in</strong>novation, marketchoice, product variety, and substitutable supply.108 <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong>


Restrictive bus<strong>in</strong>ess practices (also called ‘anticompetitive practices’) areactions by enterprises, whether <strong>in</strong> the private or public sector, designed tolimit access to markets or restra<strong>in</strong> competition <strong>in</strong> the market <strong>in</strong> order to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>or <strong>in</strong>crease their relative market position and profits without necessarilyprovid<strong>in</strong>g goods and services at a lower cost or of higher quality.Rule of reason is a regulatory approach by which competition authoritiesweigh the restra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g effects on competition and the dynamic efficiency benefitsof bus<strong>in</strong>ess behaviours to decide whether to prohibit them. In case the latterconsequences override the former effects, then those behaviours can be allowedto pass the scrut<strong>in</strong>y of competition statutes. See also Per se rule.SSequenc<strong>in</strong>g implementation of competition law is the approach adopted <strong>in</strong>some countries <strong>in</strong> the world which puts the implementation of competitionlaws <strong>in</strong>to different stages <strong>in</strong> order to maximise the effectiveness and efficiencyof their enforcement <strong>in</strong> view of the competition authorities’ limited resourcesand novelty.Substitute is a product which, by its characteristics, price, <strong>in</strong>tended use andcustomers’ patterns of purchases, can serve as a substitute for another (relevant)product thereby satisfy<strong>in</strong>g the equivalent need of the customersTTied sell<strong>in</strong>g is the practice by that customers are obliged to purchase unwantedgoods or services as a condition of purchas<strong>in</strong>g the goods or services theyreally want, typically when the supplier makes one product or service that iscritical to many customers.GLOSSARY OF TERMS USED IN TOOLKITUUnfair trade practices encompass a broad array of torts, all of which <strong>in</strong>volveeconomic <strong>in</strong>jury brought on by deceptive or wrongful conduct. The legaltheories that can be asserted <strong>in</strong>clude claims such as trade secretmisappropriation, unfair competition, false advertis<strong>in</strong>g, palm<strong>in</strong>g-off, dilutionand disparagement.VVertical agreements are contractual agreements between suppliers(manufacturers) and distributors (retailers) affect<strong>in</strong>g the conditions <strong>in</strong> whichthe parties can buy, sell or resell certa<strong>in</strong> goods or services.<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>Law</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Vietnam</strong>: A <strong>Toolkit</strong> 109

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!