11.07.2015 Views

Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the ...

Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the ...

Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Val Korah. Case Book1The complete text can be found at <strong>the</strong> following web address:http://eurlex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:C:2004:031:0005:0018:EN:PDFThe headings that are both centred and in italics are by Val Korah, <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs are part<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> guidelines, I have also italicised key words in various paragraphs anddeleted footnotes for ease <strong>of</strong> reading.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Guidelines</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>assessment</strong> <strong>of</strong> horiz<strong>on</strong>tal <strong>mergers</strong> <strong>under</strong> <strong>the</strong>Council Regulati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>trol <strong>of</strong> c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>s between<strong>under</strong>takings(2004/C 31/03)I. INTRODUCTIONMerger regulati<strong>on</strong>1. Article 2 <strong>of</strong> Council Regulati<strong>on</strong> (EC) No 139/2004 <strong>of</strong> 20 January 2004 <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>trol<strong>of</strong> c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>s between <strong>under</strong>takings 1 (hereinafter: <strong>the</strong> ‘Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong>’)provides that <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> has to appraise c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>s within <strong>the</strong> scope <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong> with a view to establishing whe<strong>the</strong>r or not <strong>the</strong>y are compatiblewith <strong>the</strong> comm<strong>on</strong> market. For that purpose, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> must assess, pursuant toArticle 2(2) and (3), whe<strong>the</strong>r or not a c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> would significantly impedeeffective competiti<strong>on</strong>, in particular as a result <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> or streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>of</strong> adominant positi<strong>on</strong>, in <strong>the</strong> comm<strong>on</strong> market or a substantial part <strong>of</strong> it.Creati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> dominant positi<strong>on</strong> <strong>under</strong> former regulati<strong>on</strong>2. Accordingly, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> must take into account any significant impediment toeffective competiti<strong>on</strong> likely to be caused by a c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>. The creati<strong>on</strong> or <strong>the</strong>streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>of</strong> a dominant positi<strong>on</strong> is a primary form <strong>of</strong> such competitive harm. The1 Council Regulati<strong>on</strong> (EC) No 139/2004 <strong>of</strong> 20 January 2004 (OJ L 24, 29.1.2004, p. 1).


Val Korah. Case Book2c<strong>on</strong>cept <strong>of</strong> dominance was defined in <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>text <strong>of</strong> Council Regulati<strong>on</strong> (EEC) No4064/89 <strong>of</strong> 21 December 1989 <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>trol <strong>of</strong> c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>s between <strong>under</strong>takings(hereinafter ‘Regulati<strong>on</strong> No 4064/89’) as:‘a situati<strong>on</strong> where <strong>on</strong>e or more <strong>under</strong>takings wield ec<strong>on</strong>omic power which wouldenable <strong>the</strong>m to prevent effective competiti<strong>on</strong> from being maintained in <strong>the</strong> relevantmarket by giving <strong>the</strong>m <strong>the</strong> opportunity to act to a c<strong>on</strong>siderable extent independently<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir competitors, <strong>the</strong>ir customers and, ultimately, <strong>of</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumers’ 2 .Dominance <strong>under</strong> current regulati<strong>on</strong>3. For <strong>the</strong> purpose <strong>of</strong> interpreting <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cept <strong>of</strong> dominance in <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>text <strong>of</strong> Regulati<strong>on</strong>No 4064/89, <strong>the</strong> Court <strong>of</strong> Justice referred to <strong>the</strong> fact that it ‘is intended to apply to allc<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>s with a Community dimensi<strong>on</strong> ins<strong>of</strong>ar as <strong>the</strong>y are likely, because <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong>ir effect <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> within <strong>the</strong> Community, to proveincompatible with <strong>the</strong> system <strong>of</strong> undistorted competiti<strong>on</strong> envisaged by <strong>the</strong> Treaty’ 3 .Indicati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> competitive harm – single or collective dominance4. The creati<strong>on</strong> or streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>of</strong> a dominant positi<strong>on</strong> held by a single firm as a result<strong>of</strong> a merger has been <strong>the</strong> most comm<strong>on</strong> basis for finding that a c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> wouldresult in a significant impediment to effective competiti<strong>on</strong>. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cept<strong>of</strong> dominance has also been applied in an oligopolistic setting to cases <strong>of</strong> collectivedominance. As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence, it is expected that most cases <strong>of</strong> incompatibility <strong>of</strong> ac<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> with <strong>the</strong> comm<strong>on</strong> market will c<strong>on</strong>tinue to be based up<strong>on</strong> a finding <strong>of</strong>dominance. That c<strong>on</strong>cept <strong>the</strong>refore provides an important indicati<strong>on</strong> as to <strong>the</strong>standard <strong>of</strong> competitive harm that is applicable when determining whe<strong>the</strong>r ac<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> is likely to impede effective competiti<strong>on</strong> to a significant degree, andhence, as to <strong>the</strong> likelihood <strong>of</strong> interventi<strong>on</strong> 4 . To that effect, <strong>the</strong> present notice isintended to preserve <strong>the</strong> guidance that can be drawn from past decisi<strong>on</strong>al practice andto take full account <strong>of</strong> past case-law <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Community Courts2 Case T-102/96, Gencor v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999] ECR II-753, paragraph 200. See Joined Cases C-68/94 and C-30/95,France and o<strong>the</strong>rs v Commissi<strong>on</strong> (hereinafter ‘Kali and Salz’), [1998] ECR I-1375, paragraph 221. In excepti<strong>on</strong>alcircumstances, a merger may give rise to <strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> or <strong>the</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>of</strong> a dominant positi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> part <strong>of</strong> an<strong>under</strong>taking which is not a party to <strong>the</strong> notified transacti<strong>on</strong> (see Case IV/M.1383 — Exx<strong>on</strong>/Mobil, points 225-229; CaseCOMP/M.2434 — Grupo Villar MIR/EnBW/Hidroelectrica del Cantabrico, points 67-71).3 See also Joined Cases C-68/94 and C-30/95, Kali and Salz, paragraph 170.4 See Recitals 25 and 26 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong>.


Val Korah. Case Book3Actual or potential competitors5. The purpose <strong>of</strong> this notice is to provide guidance as to how <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> assessesc<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>s 5 when <strong>the</strong> <strong>under</strong>takings c<strong>on</strong>cerned are actual or potential competitors<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> same relevant market 6 . In this notice such <strong>mergers</strong> will be denoted ‘horiz<strong>on</strong>tal<strong>mergers</strong>’. While <strong>the</strong> notice presents <strong>the</strong> analytical approach used by <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>in its appraisal <strong>of</strong> horiz<strong>on</strong>tal <strong>mergers</strong> it cannot provide details <strong>of</strong> all possibleapplicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>of</strong> this approach. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> applies <strong>the</strong> approach described in <strong>the</strong>notice to <strong>the</strong> particular facts and circumstances <strong>of</strong> each case.Commissi<strong>on</strong>’s evolving experience and judgments <strong>of</strong> ECJ and CFI6. The guidance set out in this notice draws and elaborates <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>'s evolvingexperience with <strong>the</strong> appraisal <strong>of</strong> horiz<strong>on</strong>tal <strong>mergers</strong> <strong>under</strong> Regulati<strong>on</strong> No 4064/89since its entry into force <strong>on</strong> 21 September 1990 as well as <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> case-law <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Court <strong>of</strong> Justice and <strong>the</strong> Court <strong>of</strong> First Instance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> European Communities. Theprinciples c<strong>on</strong>tained here will be applied and fur<strong>the</strong>r developed and refined by <strong>the</strong>Commissi<strong>on</strong> in individual cases. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> may revise this notice from time totime in <strong>the</strong> light <strong>of</strong> future developments.Subject to ECJ and CFI7. The Commissi<strong>on</strong>'s interpretati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong> as regards <strong>the</strong> appraisal <strong>of</strong>horiz<strong>on</strong>tal <strong>mergers</strong> is without prejudice to <strong>the</strong> interpretati<strong>on</strong> which may be given by<strong>the</strong> Court <strong>of</strong> Justice or <strong>the</strong> Court <strong>of</strong> First Instance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> European Communities.II. OVERVIEWBenefits <strong>of</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong>8. Effective competiti<strong>on</strong> brings benefits to c<strong>on</strong>sumers, such as low prices, high qualityproducts, a wide selecti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> goods and services, and innovati<strong>on</strong>. Through its c<strong>on</strong>trol<strong>of</strong> <strong>mergers</strong>, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> prevents <strong>mergers</strong> that would be likely to deprivecustomers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se benefits by significantly increasing <strong>the</strong> market power <strong>of</strong> firms. By5 The term ‘c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>’ used in <strong>the</strong> Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong> covers various types <strong>of</strong> transacti<strong>on</strong>s such as <strong>mergers</strong>,acquisiti<strong>on</strong>s, takeovers, and certain types <strong>of</strong> joint ventures. In <strong>the</strong> remainder <strong>of</strong> this notice, unless o<strong>the</strong>rwise specified,<strong>the</strong> term ‘merger’ will be used as a syn<strong>on</strong>ym for c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> and <strong>the</strong>refore cover all <strong>the</strong> above types <strong>of</strong> transacti<strong>on</strong>s.6 The notice does not cover <strong>the</strong> <strong>assessment</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> that a merger has in o<strong>the</strong>r markets, includingvertical and c<strong>on</strong>glomerate effects. Nor does it cover <strong>the</strong> <strong>assessment</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> a joint venture as referred to inArticle 2(4) <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong>.


Val Korah. Case Book4‘increased market power’ is meant <strong>the</strong> ability <strong>of</strong> <strong>on</strong>e or more firms to pr<strong>of</strong>itablyincrease prices, reduce output, choice or quality <strong>of</strong> goods and services, diminishinnovati<strong>on</strong>, or o<strong>the</strong>rwise influence parameters <strong>of</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong>. In this notice, <strong>the</strong>expressi<strong>on</strong> ‘increased prices’ is <strong>of</strong>ten used as shorthand for <strong>the</strong>se various ways inwhich a merger may result in competitive harm 7 . Both suppliers and buyers can havemarket power. However, for clarity, market power will usually refer here to asupplier's market power. Where a buyer's market power is <strong>the</strong> issue, <strong>the</strong> term ‘buyerpower’ is employed.Counterfactual9. In assessing <strong>the</strong> competitive effects <strong>of</strong> a merger, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> compares <strong>the</strong>competitive c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s that would result from <strong>the</strong> notified merger with <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>sthat would have prevailed without <strong>the</strong> merger 8 . In most cases <strong>the</strong> competitivec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s existing at <strong>the</strong> time <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger c<strong>on</strong>stitute <strong>the</strong> relevant comparis<strong>on</strong> forevaluating <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> a merger. However, in some circumstances, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>may take into account future changes to <strong>the</strong> market that can reas<strong>on</strong>ably be predicted 9 .It may, in particular, take account <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> likely entry or exit <strong>of</strong> firms if <strong>the</strong> merger didnot take place when c<strong>on</strong>sidering what c<strong>on</strong>stitutes <strong>the</strong> relevant comparis<strong>on</strong> 10 .Assessment – market definiti<strong>on</strong>10. The Commissi<strong>on</strong>'s <strong>assessment</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>mergers</strong> normally entails:(a) Definiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> relevant product and geographic markets;(b) Competitive <strong>assessment</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger.The main purpose <strong>of</strong> market definiti<strong>on</strong> is to identify in a systematic way <strong>the</strong> immediatecompetitive c<strong>on</strong>straints facing <strong>the</strong> merged entity. Guidance <strong>on</strong> this issue can be found in<strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>'s Notice <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> definiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> relevant market for <strong>the</strong> purposes <strong>of</strong>7 The expressi<strong>on</strong> should be <strong>under</strong>stood to also cover situati<strong>on</strong>s where, for instance, prices are decreased less, or areless likely to decrease, than <strong>the</strong>y o<strong>the</strong>rwise would have without <strong>the</strong> merger and where prices are increased more, or aremore likely to increase, than <strong>the</strong>y o<strong>the</strong>rwise would have without <strong>the</strong> merger.8 By analogy, in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> a merger that has been implemented without having been notified, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> wouldassess <strong>the</strong> merger in <strong>the</strong> light <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> competitive c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s that would have prevailed without <strong>the</strong> implemented merger.9 See, e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 98/526/EC in Case IV/M.950 — H<strong>of</strong>fmann La Roche/Boehringer Mannheim, OJ L 234,21.8.1998, p. 14, point 13; Case IV/M.1846 — Glaxo Wellcome/SmithKline Beecham, points 70-72; CaseCOMP/M.2547 — Bayer/Aventis Crop Science, points 324 et seq.10 See, e.g. Case T-102/96, Gencor v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999] ECR II-753, paragraphs 247-263.


Val Korah. Case Book5Community competiti<strong>on</strong> law (CB 98) 11 . Various c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s leading to <strong>the</strong> delineati<strong>on</strong><strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> relevant markets may also be <strong>of</strong> importance for <strong>the</strong> competitive <strong>assessment</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>merger.Elements <strong>of</strong> appraisal c<strong>on</strong>sidered in notice11. This notice is structured around <strong>the</strong> following elements:(a) The approach <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> to market shares and c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> thresholds(Secti<strong>on</strong> III).(b) The likelihood that a merger would have anticompetitive effects in <strong>the</strong> relevantmarkets, in <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> countervailing factors (Secti<strong>on</strong> IV).(c) The likelihood that buyer power would act as a countervailing factor to an increasein market power resulting from <strong>the</strong> merger (Secti<strong>on</strong> V).(d) The likelihood that entry would maintain effective competiti<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> relevantmarkets (Secti<strong>on</strong> VI).(e) The likelihood that efficiencies would act as a factor counteracting <strong>the</strong> harmfuleffects <strong>on</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> which might o<strong>the</strong>rwise result from <strong>the</strong> merger (Secti<strong>on</strong> VII).(f) The c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for a failing firm defence (Secti<strong>on</strong> VIII).Possible anti-competitive effects – countervailing factors12. In order to assess <strong>the</strong> foreseeable impact 12 <strong>of</strong> a merger <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> relevant markets, <strong>the</strong>Commissi<strong>on</strong> analyses its possible anti-competitive effects and <strong>the</strong> relevantcountervailing factors such as buyer power, <strong>the</strong> extent <strong>of</strong> entry barriers and possibleefficiencies put forward by <strong>the</strong> parties. In excepti<strong>on</strong>al circumstances, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>c<strong>on</strong>siders whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for a failing firm defence are met.13. In <strong>the</strong> light <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se elements, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> determines, pursuant to Article 2 <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong>, whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> merger would significantly impede effectivecompetiti<strong>on</strong>, in particular through <strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> or <strong>the</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>of</strong> a dominant11 OJ C 372, 9.12.1997, p. 5.12 See Case T-102/96, Gencor v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999] ECR II-753, paragraph 262, and Case T-342/99, Airtours vCommissi<strong>on</strong>, [2002] ECR II-2585,paragraph 280.


Val Korah. Case Book7light <strong>of</strong> likely market c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, for instance, if <strong>the</strong> market is highly dynamic incharacter and if <strong>the</strong> market structure is unstable due to innovati<strong>on</strong> or growth 16 .HHI c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> ratios16. The overall c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> level in a market may also provide useful informati<strong>on</strong> about<strong>the</strong> competitive situati<strong>on</strong>. In order to measure c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> levels, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong><strong>of</strong>ten applies <strong>the</strong> Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) 17 . The HHI is calculated bysumming <strong>the</strong> squares <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> individual market shares <strong>of</strong> all <strong>the</strong> firms in <strong>the</strong> market 18 .The HHI gives proporti<strong>on</strong>ately greater weight to <strong>the</strong> market shares <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> larger firms.Although it is best to include all firms in <strong>the</strong> calculati<strong>on</strong>, lack <strong>of</strong> informati<strong>on</strong> aboutvery small firms may not be important because such firms do not affect <strong>the</strong> HHIsignificantly. While <strong>the</strong> absolute level <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> HHI can give an initial indicati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>competitive pressure in <strong>the</strong> market post-merger, <strong>the</strong> change in <strong>the</strong> HHI (known as <strong>the</strong>‘delta’) is a useful proxy for <strong>the</strong> change in c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> directly brought about by <strong>the</strong>merger 19 .Market share levels17. According to well-established case law, very large market shares — 50 % or more —may in <strong>the</strong>mselves be evidence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> existence <strong>of</strong> a dominant market positi<strong>on</strong> 20 .However, smaller competitors may act as a sufficient c<strong>on</strong>straining influence if, forexample, <strong>the</strong>y have <strong>the</strong> ability and incentive to increase <strong>the</strong>ir supplies. A mergerinvolving a firm whose market share will remain below 50 % after <strong>the</strong> merger mayalso raise competiti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerns in view <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r factors such as <strong>the</strong> strength and16 See, e.g. Case COMP/M.2256 — Philips/Agilent Health Care Technologies, points 31-32, and Case COMP/M.2609— HP/Compaq, point 39.17 See, e.g. Case IV/M.1365 — FCC/Vivendi, point 40; Case COMP/JV 55 — Hutchis<strong>on</strong>/RCPM/ECT, point 50. Ifappropriate, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> may also use o<strong>the</strong>r c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> measures such as, for instance, c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> ratios,which measure <strong>the</strong> aggregate market share <strong>of</strong> a small number (usually three or four) <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> leading firms in a market.18 For example, a market c<strong>on</strong>taining five firms with market shares <strong>of</strong> 40 %, 20 %, 15 %, 15 %, and 10 %, respectively,has an HHI <strong>of</strong> 2 550 (402 + 202 + 152 + 152 + 102 = 2 550). The HHI ranges from close to zero (in an atomistic market) to10 000 (in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> a pure m<strong>on</strong>opoly).19 The increase in c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> as measured by <strong>the</strong> HHI can be calculated independently <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> overall marketc<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> by doubling <strong>the</strong> product <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market shares <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging firms. For example, a merger <strong>of</strong> two firmswith market shares <strong>of</strong> 30 % and 15 % respectively would increase <strong>the</strong> HHI by 900 (30 × 15 × 2 = 900). The explanati<strong>on</strong>for this technique is as follows: Before <strong>the</strong> merger, <strong>the</strong> market shares <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging firms c<strong>on</strong>tribute to <strong>the</strong> HHI by <strong>the</strong>irsquares individually: (a)2 + (b)2. After <strong>the</strong> merger, <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> is <strong>the</strong> square <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir sum: (a + b)2, which equals (a)2+ (b)2 + 2ab. The increase in <strong>the</strong> HHI is <strong>the</strong>refore represented by 2ab.20 Case T-221/95, Endemol v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999] ECR II-1299, paragraph 134, and Case T-102/96, Gencor vCommissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999] ECR II-753, paragraph 205. It is a distinct questi<strong>on</strong> whe<strong>the</strong>r a dominant positi<strong>on</strong> is created orstreng<strong>the</strong>ned as a result <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger.


Val Korah. Case Book8number <strong>of</strong> competitors, <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> capacity c<strong>on</strong>straints or <strong>the</strong> extent to which <strong>the</strong>products <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging parties are close substitutes. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> has thus inseveral cases c<strong>on</strong>sidered <strong>mergers</strong> resulting in firms holding market shares between 40% and 50 % 21 , and in some cases below 40 % 22 , to lead to <strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> or <strong>the</strong>streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>of</strong> a dominant positi<strong>on</strong>.Fairly safe harbour up to 25%18. C<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>s which, by reas<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> limited market share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>under</strong>takingsc<strong>on</strong>cerned, are not liable to impede effective competiti<strong>on</strong> may be presumed to becompatible with <strong>the</strong> comm<strong>on</strong> market. Without prejudice to Articles 81 and 82 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Treaty, an indicati<strong>on</strong> to this effect exists, in particular, where <strong>the</strong> market share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><strong>under</strong>takings c<strong>on</strong>cerned does not exceed 25 % 23 ei<strong>the</strong>r in <strong>the</strong> comm<strong>on</strong> market or in asubstantial part <strong>of</strong> it 24 .HHI levelsPost merger HHI <strong>under</strong> 100019. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> is unlikely to identify horiz<strong>on</strong>tal competiti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerns in a marketwith a post-merger HHI below 1 000. Such markets normally do not require extensiveanalysis.Special circumstances20. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> is also unlikely to identify horiz<strong>on</strong>tal competiti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerns in amerger with a post-merger HHI between 1 000 and 2 000 and a delta below 250, or amerger with a post-merger HHI above 2 000 and a delta below 150, except wherespecial circumstances such as, for instance, <strong>on</strong>e or more <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> following factors arepresent:21 See, e.g. Case COMP/M.2337 — Nestlé/Ralst<strong>on</strong> Purina, points 48-50.22 See, e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 1999/674/EC in Case IV/M.1221 — Rewe/Meinl, OJ L 274, 23.10.1999, p. 1, points98-114; Case COMP/M.2337 — Nestlé/Ralst<strong>on</strong> Purina, points 44-47.23 The calculati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> market shares depends critically <strong>on</strong> market definiti<strong>on</strong>. It must be emphasised that <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>does not necessarily accept <strong>the</strong> parties' proposed market definiti<strong>on</strong>.24 Recital 32 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong>. However, such an indicati<strong>on</strong> does not apply to cases where <strong>the</strong> proposedmerger creates or streng<strong>the</strong>ns a collective dominant positi<strong>on</strong> involving <strong>the</strong> ‘<strong>under</strong>takings c<strong>on</strong>cerned’ and o<strong>the</strong>r thirdparties (see Joined Cases C-68/94 and C-30/95, Kali and Salz, [1998] ECR I-1375, paragraphs 171 et seq.; and CaseT-102/96, Gencor v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999] ECR II-753, paragraphs 134 et seq.).


Val Korah. Case Book9(a) A merger involves a potential entrant or a recent entrant with a small marketshare;(b) One or more merging parties are important innovators in ways not reflected inmarket shares;(c) There are significant cross-shareholdings am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> market participants 25 ;(d) One <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging firms is a maverick firm with a high likelihood <strong>of</strong> disruptingcoordinated c<strong>on</strong>duct;(e) Indicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>of</strong> past or <strong>on</strong>going coordinati<strong>on</strong>, or facilitating practices, are present;(f) One <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging parties has a pre-merger market share <strong>of</strong> 50 % <strong>of</strong> more 26 .Use HHI <strong>on</strong>ly as initial indicator21. Each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se HHI levels, in combinati<strong>on</strong> with <strong>the</strong> relevant deltas, may be used as aninitial indicator <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerns. However, <strong>the</strong>y do not giverise to a presumpti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> existence or <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> such c<strong>on</strong>cerns.IV. POSSIBLE ANTI-COMPETITIVE EFFECTS OF HORIZONTAL MERGERS22. There are two main ways in which horiz<strong>on</strong>tal <strong>mergers</strong> may significantly impedeeffective competiti<strong>on</strong>, in particular by creating or streng<strong>the</strong>ning a dominant positi<strong>on</strong>:Unilateral effects(a) by eliminating important competitive c<strong>on</strong>straints <strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>e or more firms, whichc<strong>on</strong>sequently would have increased market power, without resorting tocoordinated behaviour (n<strong>on</strong>-coordinated effects);Co-ordinated effects =Tacit collusi<strong>on</strong>(b) by changing <strong>the</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> in such a way that firms that previouslywere not coordinating <strong>the</strong>ir behaviour, are now significantly more likely tocoordinate and raise prices or o<strong>the</strong>rwise harm effective competiti<strong>on</strong>. A merger25 In markets with cross-shareholdings or joint ventures <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> may use a modified HHI, which takes intoaccount such share-holdings (see, e.g. Case IV/M.1383 — Exx<strong>on</strong>/Mobil, point 256).26 See paragraph 17.


Val Korah. Case Book10may also make coordinati<strong>on</strong> easier, more stable or more effective for firmswhich were coordinating prior to <strong>the</strong> merger (coordinated effects).Unilateral and co-ordinated effects both relevant23. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> assesses whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> changes brought about by <strong>the</strong> merger wouldresult in any <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se effects. Both instances menti<strong>on</strong>ed above may be relevant whenassessing a particular transacti<strong>on</strong>.N<strong>on</strong>-coordinated effects 2724. A merger may significantly impede effective competiti<strong>on</strong> in a market by removingimportant competitive c<strong>on</strong>straints <strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>e or more sellers, who c<strong>on</strong>sequently haveincreased market power. The most direct effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger will be <strong>the</strong> loss <strong>of</strong>competiti<strong>on</strong> between <strong>the</strong> merging firms. For example, if prior to <strong>the</strong> merger <strong>on</strong>e <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>merging firms had raised its price, it would have lost some sales to <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r mergingfirm. The merger removes this particular c<strong>on</strong>straint. N<strong>on</strong>-merging firms in <strong>the</strong> samemarket can also benefit from <strong>the</strong> reducti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> competitive pressure that results from<strong>the</strong> merger, since <strong>the</strong> merging firms' price increase may switch some demand to <strong>the</strong>rival firms, which, in turn, may find it pr<strong>of</strong>itable to increase <strong>the</strong>ir prices 28 . Thereducti<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong>se competitive c<strong>on</strong>straints could lead to significant price increases in<strong>the</strong> relevant market.Unilateral effects25. Generally, a merger giving rise to such n<strong>on</strong>-coordinated effects would significantlyimpede effective competiti<strong>on</strong> by creating or streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong> dominant positi<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> asingle firm, <strong>on</strong>e which, typically, would have an appreciably larger market share than<strong>the</strong> next competitor post-merger. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>mergers</strong> in oligopolistic markets 29involving <strong>the</strong> eliminati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> important competitive c<strong>on</strong>straints that <strong>the</strong> merging27 Also <strong>of</strong>ten called ‘unilateral’ effects.28 Such expected reacti<strong>on</strong>s by competitors may be a relevant factor influencing <strong>the</strong> merged entity's incentives toincrease prices.29 An oligopolistic market refers to a market structure with a limited number <strong>of</strong> sizeable firms. Because <strong>the</strong> behaviour <strong>of</strong><strong>on</strong>e firm has an appreciable impact <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> overall market c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, and thus indirectly <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> situati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r firms, oligopolistic firms are interdependent.


Val Korah. Case Book11parties previously exerted up<strong>on</strong> each o<strong>the</strong>r toge<strong>the</strong>r with a reducti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> competitivepressure <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> remaining competitors may, even where <strong>the</strong>re is little likelihood <strong>of</strong>coordinati<strong>on</strong> between <strong>the</strong> members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> oligopoly, also result in a significantimpediment to competiti<strong>on</strong>. The Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong> clarifies that all <strong>mergers</strong> givingrise to such n<strong>on</strong>-coordinated effects shall also be declared incompatible with <strong>the</strong>comm<strong>on</strong> market 30 .Multiple effects26. A number <strong>of</strong> factors, which taken separately are not necessarily decisive, mayinfluence whe<strong>the</strong>r significant n<strong>on</strong>-coordinated effects are likely to result from amerger. Not all <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se factors need to be present for such effects to be likely. Norshould this be c<strong>on</strong>sidered an exhaustive list.Merging firms have large market shares27. The larger <strong>the</strong> market share, <strong>the</strong> more likely a firm is to possess market power. And<strong>the</strong> larger <strong>the</strong> additi<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> market share, <strong>the</strong> more likely it is that a merger will lead to asignificant increase in market power. The larger <strong>the</strong> increase in <strong>the</strong> sales base <strong>on</strong>which to enjoy higher margins after a price increase, <strong>the</strong> more likely it is that <strong>the</strong>merging firms will find such a price increase pr<strong>of</strong>itable despite <strong>the</strong> accompanyingreducti<strong>on</strong> in output. Although market shares and additi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>of</strong> market shares <strong>on</strong>lyprovide first indicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>of</strong> market power and increases in market power, <strong>the</strong>y arenormally important factors in <strong>the</strong> <strong>assessment</strong> 31 .Merging firms are close competitors|28. Products may be differentiated 32 within a relevant market such that some products arecloser substitutes than o<strong>the</strong>rs 33 . The higher <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> substitutability between <strong>the</strong>merging firms' products, <strong>the</strong> more likely it is that <strong>the</strong> merging firms will raise prices30 Recital 25 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong>.31 See, in particular, paragraphs 17 and 18.32 Products may be differentiated in various ways. There may, for example, be differentiati<strong>on</strong> in terms <strong>of</strong> geographiclocati<strong>on</strong>, based <strong>on</strong> branch or stores locati<strong>on</strong>; locati<strong>on</strong> matters for retail distributi<strong>on</strong>, banks, travel agencies, or petrolstati<strong>on</strong>s. Likewise, differentiati<strong>on</strong> may be based <strong>on</strong> brand image, technical specificati<strong>on</strong>s, quality or level <strong>of</strong> service. Thelevel <strong>of</strong> advertising in a market may be an indicator <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firms' effort to differentiate <strong>the</strong>ir products. For o<strong>the</strong>r products,buyers may have to incur switching costs to use a competitor's product.33 For <strong>the</strong> definiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> relevant market, see <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>'s Notice <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> definiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> relevant market for <strong>the</strong>purposes <strong>of</strong> Community competiti<strong>on</strong> law, cited above.


Val Korah. Case Book12significantly 34 . For example, a merger between two producers <strong>of</strong>fering products whicha substantial number <strong>of</strong> customers regard as <strong>the</strong>ir first and sec<strong>on</strong>d choices couldgenerate a significant price increase. Thus, <strong>the</strong> fact that rivalry between <strong>the</strong> parties hasbeen an important source <strong>of</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> market may be a central factor in <strong>the</strong>analysis 35 . High pre-merger margins 36 may also make significant price increases morelikely. The merging firms' incentive to raise prices is more likely to be c<strong>on</strong>strainedwhen rival firms produce close substitutes to <strong>the</strong> products <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging firms thanwhen <strong>the</strong>y <strong>of</strong>fer less close substitutes 37 . It is <strong>the</strong>refore less likely that a merger willsignificantly impede effective competiti<strong>on</strong>, in particular through <strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> orstreng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>of</strong> a dominant positi<strong>on</strong>, when <strong>the</strong>re is a high degree <strong>of</strong> substitutabilitybetween <strong>the</strong> products <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging firms and those supplied by rival producers.Degree <strong>of</strong> substitutability29. When data are available, <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> substitutability may be evaluated throughcustomer preference surveys, analysis <strong>of</strong> purchasing patterns, estimati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> crosspriceelasticities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> products involved 38 , or diversi<strong>on</strong> ratios 39 . In bidding markets itmay be possible to measure whe<strong>the</strong>r historically <strong>the</strong> submitted bids by <strong>on</strong>e <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>merging parties have been c<strong>on</strong>strained by <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r merging party 40 .Possibility <strong>of</strong> repositi<strong>on</strong>ing or extending product line30. In some markets it may be relatively easy and not too costly for <strong>the</strong> active firms torepositi<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir products or extend <strong>the</strong>ir product portfolio. In particular, <strong>the</strong>34 See for example Case COMP/M.2817 — Barilla/BPS/Kamps, point 34; Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2001/403/EC in CaseCOMP/M.1672 — Volvo/ Scania, OJ L 143, 29.5.2001, p. 74, points 107-148.35 See, e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 94/893/EC in Case IV/M.430 — Procter & Gamble/VP Schickedanz (II), OJ L 354,21.6.1994, p. 32, Case T-290/94, Kaysersberg v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1997] II-2137, paragraph 153; Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong>97/610/EC in Case IV/M.774 — Saint-Gobain/ Wacker-Chemie/NOM, OJ L 247, 10.9.1997, p. 1, point 179; Commissi<strong>on</strong>Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2002/156/EC in Case COMP/M.2097 — SCA/Metsä Tissue, OJ L 57, 27.2.2002, p. 1, points 94-108; Case T-310/01, Schneider v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [2002] II-4071, paragraph 418.36 Typically, <strong>the</strong> relevant margin (m) is <strong>the</strong> difference between price (p) and <strong>the</strong> incremental cost (c) <strong>of</strong> supplying <strong>on</strong>emore unit <strong>of</strong> output expressed as a percentage <strong>of</strong> price (m = (p - c)p)).37 See, e.g. Case IV/M.1980 — Volvo/Renault VI, point 34; Case COMP/M.2256 — Philips Agilent/Health CareSoluti<strong>on</strong>s, points 33-35; Case COMP/M.2537 — Philips/Marc<strong>on</strong>i Medical Systems, points 31-34.38 The cross-price elasticity <strong>of</strong> demand measures <strong>the</strong> extent to which <strong>the</strong> quantity <strong>of</strong> a product demanded changes inresp<strong>on</strong>se to a change in <strong>the</strong> price <strong>of</strong> some o<strong>the</strong>r product, all o<strong>the</strong>r things remaining equal. The own-price elasticitymeasures <strong>the</strong> extent to which demand for a product changes in resp<strong>on</strong>se to <strong>the</strong> change in <strong>the</strong> price <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> product itself.39 The diversi<strong>on</strong> ratio from product A to product B measures <strong>the</strong> proporti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> sales <strong>of</strong> product A lost due to a priceincrease <strong>of</strong> A that are captured by product B.40 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 97/816/EC in Case IV/M.877 — Boeing/McD<strong>on</strong>nell Douglas, OJ L 336, 8.12.1997, p. 16, points58 et seq.; Case COMP/M.3083 — GE/Instrumentarium, points 125 et seq.


Val Korah. Case Book13Commissi<strong>on</strong> examines whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> possibility <strong>of</strong> repositi<strong>on</strong>ing or product lineextensi<strong>on</strong> by competitors or <strong>the</strong> merging parties may influence <strong>the</strong> incentive <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>merged entity to raise prices. However, product repositi<strong>on</strong>ing or product lineextensi<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong>ten entails risks and large sunk costs 41 and may be less pr<strong>of</strong>itable than <strong>the</strong>current line.Customers have limited possibilities <strong>of</strong> switching supplier31. Customers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging parties may have difficulties switching to o<strong>the</strong>r suppliersbecause <strong>the</strong>re are few alternative suppliers 42 or because <strong>the</strong>y face substantialswitching costs 43 . Such customers are particularly vulnerable to price increases. Themerger may affect <strong>the</strong>se customers' ability to protect <strong>the</strong>mselves against priceincreases. In particular, this may be <strong>the</strong> case for customers that have used dualsourcing from <strong>the</strong> two merging firms as a means <strong>of</strong> obtaining competitive prices.Evidence <strong>of</strong> past customer switching patterns and reacti<strong>on</strong>s to price changes mayprovide important informati<strong>on</strong> in this respect.Competitors are unlikely to increase supply if prices increase32. When market c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s are such that <strong>the</strong> competitors <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging parties areunlikely to increase <strong>the</strong>ir supply substantially if prices increase, <strong>the</strong> merging firmsmay have an incentive to reduce output below <strong>the</strong> combined pre-merger levels,<strong>the</strong>reby raising market prices 44 . The merger increases <strong>the</strong> incentive to reduce outputby giving <strong>the</strong> merged firm a larger base <strong>of</strong> sales <strong>on</strong> which to enjoy <strong>the</strong> higher marginsresulting from an increase in prices induced by <strong>the</strong> output reducti<strong>on</strong>.Rivals’ capacity to expand when prices rise33. C<strong>on</strong>versely, when market c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s are such that rival firms have enough capacityand find it pr<strong>of</strong>itable to expand output sufficiently, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> is unlikely to findthat <strong>the</strong> merger will create or streng<strong>the</strong>n a dominant positi<strong>on</strong> or o<strong>the</strong>rwisesignificantly impede effective competiti<strong>on</strong>.41 Sunk costs are costs which are unrecoverable up<strong>on</strong> exit from <strong>the</strong> market.42 See e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2002/156/EC in Case IV/M.877 — Boeing/McD<strong>on</strong>nell Douglas, OJ L 336, 8.12.1997,p. 16, point 70.43 See, e.g. Case IV/M. 986 — Agfa Gevaert/DuP<strong>on</strong>t, OJ L 211, 29.7.1998, p. 22, points 63-71.44 See, e.g. Case COMP/M.2187 — CVC/Lenzing, points 162-170.


Val Korah. Case Book14Rivals’ capacity c<strong>on</strong>straints34. Such output expansi<strong>on</strong> is, in particular, unlikely when competitors face bindingcapacity c<strong>on</strong>straints and <strong>the</strong> expansi<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> capacity is costly 45 or if existing excesscapacity is significantly more costly to operate than capacity currently in use.Homogenous and differentiated products35. Although capacity c<strong>on</strong>straints are more likely to be important when goods arerelatively homogeneous, <strong>the</strong>y may also be important where firms <strong>of</strong>fer differentiatedproducts.Merged entity able to hinder expansi<strong>on</strong> by competitors36. Some proposed <strong>mergers</strong> would, if allowed to proceed, significantly impede effectivecompetiti<strong>on</strong> by leaving <strong>the</strong> merged firm in a positi<strong>on</strong> where it would have <strong>the</strong> abilityand incentive to make <strong>the</strong> expansi<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> smaller firms and potential competitors moredifficult or o<strong>the</strong>rwise restrict <strong>the</strong> ability <strong>of</strong> rival firms to compete. In such a case,competitors may not, ei<strong>the</strong>r individually or in <strong>the</strong> aggregate, be in a positi<strong>on</strong> toc<strong>on</strong>strain <strong>the</strong> merged entity to such a degree that it would not increase prices or takeo<strong>the</strong>r acti<strong>on</strong>s detrimental to competiti<strong>on</strong>. For instance, <strong>the</strong> merged entity may havesuch a degree <strong>of</strong> c<strong>on</strong>trol, or influence over, <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> inputs 46 or distributi<strong>on</strong>possibilities 47 that expansi<strong>on</strong> or entry by rival firms may be more costly. Similarly, <strong>the</strong>merged entity's c<strong>on</strong>trol over patents 48 or o<strong>the</strong>r types <strong>of</strong> intellectual property (e.g.brands 49 ) may make expansi<strong>on</strong> or entry by rivals more difficult. In markets whereinteroperability between different infrastructures or platforms is important 50 , a mergermay give <strong>the</strong> merged entity <strong>the</strong> ability and incentive to raise <strong>the</strong> costs or decrease <strong>the</strong>45 When analysing <strong>the</strong> possible expansi<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> capacity by rivals, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>siders factors similar to thosedescribed in Secti<strong>on</strong> VI <strong>on</strong> entry. See, e.g. Case COMP/M.2187 — CVC/Lenzing, points 162-173.46 See, e.g. Case T-221/95, Endemol v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999] ECR II-1299, paragraph 167.47 See, e.g. Case T-22/97, Kesko v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999], ECR II-3775, paragraphs 141 et seq.48 See, e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2001/684/EC in Case M.1671 — Dow Chemical/Uni<strong>on</strong> Carbide OJ L 245, 14.9.2001,p. 1, points 107-114.49 See, e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 96/435/EC in Case IV/M.623 — Kimberly-Clark/Scott, OJ L 183, 23.7.1996, p. 1;Case T-114/02, Babyliss SA v Commissi<strong>on</strong> (‘Seb/Moulinex’), [2003] ECR II-000, paragraphs 343 et seq.50 This is, for example, <strong>the</strong> case in network industries such as energy, telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s and o<strong>the</strong>r communicati<strong>on</strong>industries.


Val Korah. Case Book15quality <strong>of</strong> service <strong>of</strong> its rivals 51 . In making this <strong>assessment</strong> <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> may takeinto account, inter alia, <strong>the</strong> financial strength <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merged entity relative to itsrivals 52 .Merger eliminates an important competitive force37. Some firms have more <strong>of</strong> an influence <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> competitive process than <strong>the</strong>ir marketshares or similar measures would suggest. A merger involving such a firm maychange <strong>the</strong> competitive dynamics in a significant, anticompetitive way, in particularwhen <strong>the</strong> market is already c<strong>on</strong>centrated 53 . For instance, a firm may be a recententrant that is expected to exert significant competitive pressure in <strong>the</strong> future <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r firms in <strong>the</strong> market.Innovati<strong>on</strong>38. In markets where innovati<strong>on</strong> is an important competitive force, a merger may increase<strong>the</strong> firms' ability and incentive to bring new innovati<strong>on</strong>s to <strong>the</strong> market and, <strong>the</strong>reby,<strong>the</strong> competitive pressure <strong>on</strong> rivals to innovate in that market. Alternatively, effectivecompetiti<strong>on</strong> may be significantly impeded by a merger between two importantinnovators, for instance between two companies with ‘pipeline’ products related to aspecific product market. Similarly, a firm with a relatively small market share maynever<strong>the</strong>less be an important competitive force if it has promising pipeline products 54 .Coordinated effectsCollective dominant positi<strong>on</strong> – tacit collusi<strong>on</strong>39. In some markets <strong>the</strong> structure may be such that firms would c<strong>on</strong>sider it possible,ec<strong>on</strong>omically rati<strong>on</strong>al, and hence preferable, to adopt <strong>on</strong> a sustainable basis a course<strong>of</strong> acti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> market aimed at selling at increased prices. A merger in ac<strong>on</strong>centrated market may significantly impede effective competiti<strong>on</strong>, through <strong>the</strong>51 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 99/287/EC in Case IV/M.1069 — Worldcom/MCI, OJ L 116, 4.5.1999, p. 1, points 117 et seq.;Case IV/M.1741 — MCI Worldcom/Sprint, points 145 et seq.; Case IV/M.1795 — Vodaf<strong>on</strong>e Airtouch/Mannesmann,points 44 et seq.52 Case T-156/98 RJB Mining v Commissi<strong>on</strong> [2001] ECR II-337.53 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2002/156/EC in Case IV/M.877 — Boeing/McD<strong>on</strong>nell Douglas, OJ L 336, 8.12.1997, p. 16,point 58; Case COMP/M.2568 — Haniel/Yt<strong>on</strong>g, point 126.54 For an example <strong>of</strong> pipeline products <strong>of</strong> <strong>on</strong>e merging party likely to compete with <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r party's pipeline or existingproducts, see, e.g. Case IV/M.1846 — Glaxo Wellcome/SmithKline Beecham, point 188.


Val Korah. Case Book16creati<strong>on</strong> or <strong>the</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>of</strong> a collective dominant positi<strong>on</strong>, because it increases<strong>the</strong> likelihood that firms are able to coordinate <strong>the</strong>ir behaviour in this way and raiseprices, even without entering into an agreement or resorting to a c<strong>on</strong>certed practicewithin <strong>the</strong> meaning <strong>of</strong> Article 81 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Treaty 55 . A merger may also makecoordinati<strong>on</strong> easier, more stable or more effective for firms that were alreadycoordinating before <strong>the</strong> merger, ei<strong>the</strong>r by making <strong>the</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong> more robust or bypermitting firms to coordinate <strong>on</strong> even higher prices.Forms <strong>of</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong>40. Coordinati<strong>on</strong> may take various forms. In some markets, <strong>the</strong> most likely coordinati<strong>on</strong>may involve keeping prices above <strong>the</strong> competitive level. In o<strong>the</strong>r markets,coordinati<strong>on</strong> may aim at limiting producti<strong>on</strong> or <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> new capacity broughtto <strong>the</strong> market. Firms may also coordinate by dividing <strong>the</strong> market, for instance bygeographic area 56 or o<strong>the</strong>r customer characteristics, or by allocating c<strong>on</strong>tracts inbidding markets.C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for coordinati<strong>on</strong>41. Coordinati<strong>on</strong> is more likely to emerge in markets where it is relatively simple to reacha comm<strong>on</strong> <strong>under</strong>standing <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong>. In additi<strong>on</strong>, three c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>sare necessary for coordinati<strong>on</strong> to be sustainable. First, <strong>the</strong> coordinating firms must beable to m<strong>on</strong>itor to a sufficient degree whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong> are beingadhered to. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, discipline requires that <strong>the</strong>re is some form <strong>of</strong> credible deterrentmechanism that can be activated if deviati<strong>on</strong> is detected. Third, <strong>the</strong> reacti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>of</strong>outsiders, such as current and future competitors not participating in <strong>the</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong>,as well as customers, should not be able to jeopardise <strong>the</strong> results expected from <strong>the</strong>coordinati<strong>on</strong> 57 .Whe<strong>the</strong>r parties can agree <strong>on</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong> & sustain it42. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> examines whe<strong>the</strong>r it would be possible to reach terms <strong>of</strong>coordinati<strong>on</strong> and whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be sustainable. In this respect,55 Case T-102/96, Gencor v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999] ECR II-753, paragraph 277; Case T-342/99, Airtours v Commissi<strong>on</strong>,[2002] ECR II-2585, paragraph 61.56 This may be <strong>the</strong> case if <strong>the</strong> oligopolists have tended to c<strong>on</strong>centrate <strong>the</strong>ir sales in different areas for historic reas<strong>on</strong>s.57 Case T-342/99, Airtours v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [2002] ECR II-2585, paragraph 62.


Val Korah. Case Book17<strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>siders <strong>the</strong> changes that <strong>the</strong> merger brings about. The reducti<strong>on</strong> in<strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> firms in a market may, in itself, be a factor that facilitates coordinati<strong>on</strong>.However, a merger may also increase <strong>the</strong> likelihood or significance <strong>of</strong> coordinatedeffects in o<strong>the</strong>r ways. For instance, a merger may involve a ‘maverick’ firm that has ahistory <strong>of</strong> preventing or disrupting coordinati<strong>on</strong>, for example by failing to followprice increases by its competitors, or has characteristics that gives it an incentive t<strong>of</strong>avour different strategic choices than its coordinating competitors would prefer. If<strong>the</strong> merged firm were to adopt strategies similar to those <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r competitors, <strong>the</strong>remaining firms would find it easier to coordinate, and <strong>the</strong> merger would increase <strong>the</strong>likelihood, stability or effectiveness <strong>of</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong>.Structure <strong>of</strong> market and past behaviour <strong>of</strong> firms43. In assessing <strong>the</strong> likelihood <strong>of</strong> coordinated effects, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> takes into accountall available relevant informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> markets c<strong>on</strong>cerned,including both structural features and <strong>the</strong> past behaviour <strong>of</strong> firms 58 . Evidence <strong>of</strong> pastcoordinati<strong>on</strong> is important if <strong>the</strong> relevant market characteristics have not changedappreciably or are not likely to do so in <strong>the</strong> near future 59 . Likewise, evidence <strong>of</strong>coordinati<strong>on</strong> in similar markets may be useful informati<strong>on</strong>.Reaching terms <strong>of</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong>44. Coordinati<strong>on</strong> is more likely to emerge if competitors can easily arrive at a comm<strong>on</strong>percepti<strong>on</strong> as to how <strong>the</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong> should work. Coordinating firms should havesimilar views regarding which acti<strong>on</strong>s would be c<strong>on</strong>sidered to be in accordance with<strong>the</strong> aligned behaviour and which acti<strong>on</strong>s would not.Relevant factors45. Generally, <strong>the</strong> less complex and <strong>the</strong> more stable <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic envir<strong>on</strong>ment, <strong>the</strong> easierit is for <strong>the</strong> firms to reach a comm<strong>on</strong> <strong>under</strong>standing <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong>. Forinstance, it is easier to coordinate am<strong>on</strong>g a few players than am<strong>on</strong>g many. It is alsoeasier to coordinate <strong>on</strong> a price for a single, homogeneous product, than <strong>on</strong> hundreds <strong>of</strong>prices in a market with many differentiated products. Similarly, it is easier to58 See Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 92/553/EC in Case IV/M.190 — Nestlé/Perrier, OJ L 356, 5.12.1992, p. 1, points 117-118.59 See, e.g. Case IV/M.580 — ABB/Daimler-Benz, point 95.


Val Korah. Case Book18coordinate <strong>on</strong> a price when demand and supply c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s are relatively stable thanwhen <strong>the</strong>y are c<strong>on</strong>tinuously changing 60 . In this c<strong>on</strong>text volatile demand, substantialinternal growth by some firms in <strong>the</strong> market or frequent entry by new firms mayindicate that <strong>the</strong> current situati<strong>on</strong> is not sufficiently stable to make coordinati<strong>on</strong>likely 61 . In markets where innovati<strong>on</strong> is important, coordinati<strong>on</strong> may be more difficultsince innovati<strong>on</strong>s, particularly significant <strong>on</strong>es, may allow <strong>on</strong>e firm to gain a majoradvantage over its rivals.Market allocati<strong>on</strong>46. Coordinati<strong>on</strong> by way <strong>of</strong> market divisi<strong>on</strong> will be easier if customers have simplecharacteristics that allow <strong>the</strong> coordinating firms to readily allocate <strong>the</strong>m. Suchcharacteristics may be based <strong>on</strong> geography; <strong>on</strong> customer type or simply <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>existence <strong>of</strong> customers who typically buy from <strong>on</strong>e specific firm. Coordinati<strong>on</strong> byway <strong>of</strong> market divisi<strong>on</strong> may be relatively straightforward if it is easy to identify eachcustomer's supplier and <strong>the</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong> device is <strong>the</strong> allocati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> existing customersto <strong>the</strong>ir incumbent supplier.Ways <strong>of</strong> simplifying coordinati<strong>on</strong>47. Coordinating firms may, however, find o<strong>the</strong>r ways to overcome problems stemmingfrom complex ec<strong>on</strong>omic envir<strong>on</strong>ments short <strong>of</strong> market divisi<strong>on</strong>. They may, forinstance, establish simple pricing rules that reduce <strong>the</strong> complexity <strong>of</strong> coordinating <strong>on</strong>a large number <strong>of</strong> prices. One example <strong>of</strong> such a rule is establishing a small number<strong>of</strong> pricing points, thus reducing <strong>the</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong> problem. Ano<strong>the</strong>r example is havinga fixed relati<strong>on</strong>ship between certain base prices and a number <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r prices, suchthat prices basically move in parallel. Publicly available key informati<strong>on</strong>, exchange <strong>of</strong>informati<strong>on</strong> through trade associati<strong>on</strong>s, or informati<strong>on</strong> received through crossshareholdingsor participati<strong>on</strong> in joint ventures may also help firms reach terms <strong>of</strong>coordinati<strong>on</strong>. The more complex <strong>the</strong> market situati<strong>on</strong> is, <strong>the</strong> more transparency orcommunicati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be needed to reach a comm<strong>on</strong> <strong>under</strong>standing <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> terms<strong>of</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong>.Symmetry, cross-share holding and joint ventures60 See, e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2002/156/EC in Case COMP/M.2097 — SCA/Metsä Tissue, OJ L 57, 27.2.2002, p. 1,point 148.61 See, e.g. Case IV/M.1298 — Kodak/Imati<strong>on</strong>, point 60.


Val Korah. Case Book1948. Firms may find it easier to reach a comm<strong>on</strong> <strong>under</strong>standing <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>of</strong>coordinati<strong>on</strong> if <strong>the</strong>y are relatively symmetric 62 , especially in terms <strong>of</strong> cost structures,market shares, capacity levels and levels <strong>of</strong> vertical integrati<strong>on</strong> 63 . Structural links suchas cross-shareholding or participati<strong>on</strong> in joint ventures may also help in aligningincentives am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>the</strong> coordinating firms 64 .M<strong>on</strong>itoring deviati<strong>on</strong>sRetaliati<strong>on</strong>49. Coordinating firms are <strong>of</strong>ten tempted to increase <strong>the</strong>ir share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market bydeviating from <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong>, for instance by lowering prices, <strong>of</strong>feringsecret discounts, increasing product quality or capacity or trying to win newcustomers. Only <strong>the</strong> credible threat <strong>of</strong> timely and sufficient retaliati<strong>on</strong> keeps firmsfrom deviating. Markets <strong>the</strong>refore need to be sufficiently transparent to allow <strong>the</strong>coordinating firms to m<strong>on</strong>itor to a sufficient degree whe<strong>the</strong>r o<strong>the</strong>r firms are deviating,and thus know when to retaliate 65 .Transparency50. Transparency in <strong>the</strong> market is <strong>of</strong>ten higher, <strong>the</strong> lower <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> activeparticipants in <strong>the</strong> market. Fur<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> transparency <strong>of</strong>ten depends <strong>on</strong> howmarket transacti<strong>on</strong>s take place in a particular market. For example, transparency islikely to be high in a market where transacti<strong>on</strong>s take place <strong>on</strong> a public exchange or inan open outcry aucti<strong>on</strong> 66 . C<strong>on</strong>versely, transparency may be low in a market wheretransacti<strong>on</strong>s are c<strong>on</strong>fidentially negotiated between buyers and sellers <strong>on</strong> a bilateralbasis 67 . When evaluating <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> transparency in <strong>the</strong> market, <strong>the</strong> key element is toidentify what firms can infer about <strong>the</strong> acti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r firms from <strong>the</strong> available62 Case T-102/96, Gencor v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999] ECR II-753, paragraph 222; Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 92/553/EC in CaseIV/M.190 — Nestlé/Perrier, OJ L 356, 5.12.1992, p. 1, points 63-123.63 In assessing whe<strong>the</strong>r or not a merger may increase <strong>the</strong> symmetry <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> various firms present <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> market,efficiency gains may provide important indicati<strong>on</strong>s (see also paragraph 82 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> notice).64 See, e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2001/519/EC in Case COMP/M.1673 — VEBA/VIAG, OJ L 188, 10.7.2001, p. 1, point226; Case COMP/M.2567 — Nordbanken/Postgirot, point 54.65 See, e.g. Case COMP/M.2389 — Shell/DEA, points 112 et seq.; and Case COMP/M.2533 — BP/E.ON, points 102 etseq.66 See also Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2000/42/EC in Case IV/M.1313 — Danish Crown/Vestjyske Slagterier, OJ L 20,25.1.2000, p. 1, points 176-179.67 See, e.g. Case COMP/M.2640 — Nestlé/Schöller, point 37; Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 1999/641/EC in CaseCOMP/M.1225 — Enso/Stora, OJ L 254, 29.9.1999, p. 9, points 67-68.


Val Korah. Case Book20informati<strong>on</strong> 68 . Coordinating firms should be able to interpret with some certaintywhe<strong>the</strong>r unexpected behaviour is <strong>the</strong> result <strong>of</strong> deviati<strong>on</strong> from <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>of</strong>coordinati<strong>on</strong>. For instance, in unstable envir<strong>on</strong>ments it may be difficult for a firm toknow whe<strong>the</strong>r its lost sales are due to an overall low level <strong>of</strong> demand or due to acompetitor <strong>of</strong>fering particularly low prices. Similarly, when overall demand or costc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s fluctuate, it may be difficult to interpret whe<strong>the</strong>r a competitor is loweringits price because it expects <strong>the</strong> coordinated prices to fall or because it is deviating.Facilitating devices that ease m<strong>on</strong>itoring51. In some markets where <strong>the</strong> general c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s may seem to make m<strong>on</strong>itoring <strong>of</strong>deviati<strong>on</strong>s difficult, firms may never<strong>the</strong>less engage in practices which have <strong>the</strong> effect<strong>of</strong> easing <strong>the</strong> m<strong>on</strong>itoring task, even when <strong>the</strong>se practices are not necessarily enteredinto for such purposes. These practices, such as meeting-competiti<strong>on</strong> or mostfavoured-customerclauses, voluntary publicati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> informati<strong>on</strong>, announcements, orexchange <strong>of</strong> informati<strong>on</strong> through trade associati<strong>on</strong>s, may increase transparency orhelp competitors interpret <strong>the</strong> choices made. Cross-directorships, participati<strong>on</strong> injoint ventures and similar arrangements may also make m<strong>on</strong>itoring easier.Deterrent mechanismsCertainty <strong>of</strong> punishment52. Coordinati<strong>on</strong> is not sustainable unless <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sequences <strong>of</strong> deviati<strong>on</strong> are sufficientlysevere to c<strong>on</strong>vince coordinating firms that it is in <strong>the</strong>ir best interest to adhere to <strong>the</strong>terms <strong>of</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong>. It is thus <strong>the</strong> threat <strong>of</strong> future retaliati<strong>on</strong> that keeps <strong>the</strong>coordinati<strong>on</strong> sustainable 69 . However <strong>the</strong> threat is <strong>on</strong>ly credible if, where deviati<strong>on</strong> by<strong>on</strong>e <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firms is detected, <strong>the</strong>re is sufficient certainty that some deterrentmechanism will be activated 70 .Time lag – lumpy orders68 See, e.g. Case IV/M.1939 — Rexam (PLM)/American Nati<strong>on</strong>al Can, point 24.69 See Case COMP/M.2389 — Shell/DEA, point 121, and Case COMP/M.2533 — BP/E.ON, point 111.70 Although deterrent mechanisms are sometimes called ‘punishment’ mechanisms, this should not be <strong>under</strong>stood in <strong>the</strong>strict sense that such a mechanism necessarily punishes individually a firm that has deviated. The expectati<strong>on</strong> thatcoordinati<strong>on</strong> may break down for a certain period <strong>of</strong> time, if a deviati<strong>on</strong> is identified as such, may in itself c<strong>on</strong>stitute asufficient deterrent mechanism.


Val Korah. Case Book2153. Retaliati<strong>on</strong> that manifests itself after some significant time lag, or is not certain to beactivated, is less likely to be sufficient to <strong>of</strong>fset <strong>the</strong> benefits from deviating. Forexample, if a market is characterised by infrequent, large-volume orders, it may bedifficult to establish a sufficiently severe deterrent mechanism, since <strong>the</strong> gain fromdeviating at <strong>the</strong> right time may be large, certain and immediate, whereas <strong>the</strong> lossesfrom being punished may be small and uncertain and <strong>on</strong>ly materialise after some time.The speed with which deterrent mechanisms can be implemented is related to <strong>the</strong>issue <strong>of</strong> transparency. If firms are <strong>on</strong>ly able to observe <strong>the</strong>ir competitors' acti<strong>on</strong>s aftera substantial delay, <strong>the</strong>n retaliati<strong>on</strong> will be similarly delayed and this may influencewhe<strong>the</strong>r it is sufficient to deter deviati<strong>on</strong>.Incentive to retaliate54. The credibility <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> deterrence mechanism depends <strong>on</strong> whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rcoordinating firms have an incentive to retaliate. Some deterrent mechanisms, such aspunishing <strong>the</strong> deviator by temporarily engaging in a price war or increasing outputsignificantly, may entail a short-term ec<strong>on</strong>omic loss for <strong>the</strong> firms carrying out <strong>the</strong>retaliati<strong>on</strong>. This does not necessarily remove <strong>the</strong> incentive to retaliate since <strong>the</strong> shorttermloss may be smaller than <strong>the</strong> l<strong>on</strong>g-term benefit <strong>of</strong> retaliating resulting from <strong>the</strong>return to <strong>the</strong> regime <strong>of</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong>.In <strong>the</strong> same or ano<strong>the</strong>r market55. Retaliati<strong>on</strong> need not necessarily take place in <strong>the</strong> same market as <strong>the</strong> deviati<strong>on</strong> 71 . If<strong>the</strong> coordinating firms have commercial interacti<strong>on</strong> in o<strong>the</strong>r markets, <strong>the</strong>se may <strong>of</strong>fervarious methods <strong>of</strong> retaliati<strong>on</strong> 72 . The retaliati<strong>on</strong> could take many forms, includingcancellati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> joint ventures or o<strong>the</strong>r forms <strong>of</strong> cooperati<strong>on</strong> or selling <strong>of</strong> shares injointly owned companies.Reacti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>of</strong> outsidersBy competitors, actual or potential, and customers56. For coordinati<strong>on</strong> to be successful, <strong>the</strong> acti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>of</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-coordinating firms and potentialcompetitors, as well as customers, should not be able to jeopardise <strong>the</strong> outcome71 See, e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2000/42/EC in Case IV/M.1313 — Danish Crown/Vestjyske Slagterier, OJ L 20,25.1.2000, p. 1, point 177.72 See Case T-102/96, Gencor v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999] ECR II-753, paragraph 281.


Val Korah. Case Book22expected from coordinati<strong>on</strong>. For example, if coordinati<strong>on</strong> aims at reducing overallcapacity in <strong>the</strong> market, this will <strong>on</strong>ly hurt c<strong>on</strong>sumers if n<strong>on</strong>-coordinating firms areunable or have no incentive to resp<strong>on</strong>d to this decrease by increasing <strong>the</strong>ir owncapacity sufficiently to prevent a net decrease in capacity, or at least to render <strong>the</strong>coordinated capacity decrease unpr<strong>of</strong>itable 73 .Buyer power57. The effects <strong>of</strong> entry and countervailing buyer power <strong>of</strong> customers are analysed in latersecti<strong>on</strong>s (Points 61-67). However, special c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> is given to <strong>the</strong> possibleimpact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se elements <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> stability <strong>of</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong>. For instance, byc<strong>on</strong>centrating a large amount <strong>of</strong> its requirements with <strong>on</strong>e supplier or by <strong>of</strong>feringl<strong>on</strong>g-term c<strong>on</strong>tracts, a large buyer may make coordinati<strong>on</strong> unstable by successfullytempting <strong>on</strong>e <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> coordinating firms to deviate in order to gain substantial newbusiness.Merger with a potential competitorMerger with potential competitor58. C<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>s where an <strong>under</strong>taking already active <strong>on</strong> a relevant market merges witha potential competitor in this market can have similar anti-competitive effects to<strong>mergers</strong> between two <strong>under</strong>takings already active <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> same relevant market and,thus, significantly impede effective competiti<strong>on</strong>, in particular through <strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> or<strong>the</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>of</strong> a dominant positi<strong>on</strong>.Absence <strong>of</strong> sunk switching costs for potential competitor59. A merger with a potential competitor can generate horiz<strong>on</strong>tal anti-competitive effects,whe<strong>the</strong>r coordinated or n<strong>on</strong>-coordinated, if <strong>the</strong> potential competitor significantlyc<strong>on</strong>strains <strong>the</strong> behaviour <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firms active in <strong>the</strong> market. This is <strong>the</strong> case if <strong>the</strong>potential competitor possesses assets that could easily be used to enter <strong>the</strong> marketwithout incurring significant sunk costs. Anticompetitive effects may also occurwhere <strong>the</strong> merging partner is very likely to incur <strong>the</strong> necessary sunk costs to enter <strong>the</strong>73 These elements are analysed in a similar way to n<strong>on</strong>-coordinated effects.


Val Korah. Case Book23market in a relatively short period <strong>of</strong> time after which this company would c<strong>on</strong>strain<strong>the</strong> behaviour <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firms currently active in <strong>the</strong> market 74 .Two basic c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for merger with potential competitor to have significant anticompetitiveeffects60. For a merger with a potential competitor to have significant anti-competitive effects,two basic c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s must be fulfilled. First, <strong>the</strong> potential competitor must alreadyexert a significant c<strong>on</strong>straining influence or <strong>the</strong>re must be a significant likelihood thatit would grow into an effective competitive force. Evidence that a potential competitorhas plans to enter a market in a significant way could help <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> to reachsuch a c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> 75 . Sec<strong>on</strong>d, <strong>the</strong>re must not be a sufficient number <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r potentialcompetitors, which could maintain sufficient competitive pressure after <strong>the</strong> merger 76 .Mergers creating or streng<strong>the</strong>ning buyer power in upstream marketsDetriments to competiti<strong>on</strong>61. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> may also analyse to what extent a merged entity will increase itsbuyer power in upstream markets. On <strong>the</strong> <strong>on</strong>e hand, a merger that creates orstreng<strong>the</strong>ns <strong>the</strong> market power <strong>of</strong> a buyer may significantly impede effectivecompetiti<strong>on</strong>, in particular by creating or streng<strong>the</strong>ning a dominant positi<strong>on</strong>. Themerged firm may be in a positi<strong>on</strong> to obtain lower prices by reducing its purchase <strong>of</strong>inputs. This may, in turn, lead it also to lower its level <strong>of</strong> output in <strong>the</strong> final productmarket, and thus harm c<strong>on</strong>sumer welfare 77 . Such effects may in particular arise whenupstream sellers are relatively fragmented. Competiti<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> downstream marketscould also be adversely affected if, in particular, <strong>the</strong> merged entity was likely to use itsbuyer power vis-à-vis its suppliers to foreclose its rivals 78 .Benefits to c<strong>on</strong>sumers74 See, e.g. Case IV/M.1630 — Air Liquide/BOC, points 201 et seq. For an example <strong>of</strong> a case where entry by <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rmerging firm was not sufficiently likely in <strong>the</strong> short to medium term (Case T-158/00, ARD v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [2003] ECR II-000, paragraphs 115-127).75 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2001/98/EC in Case IV/M.1439 — Telia/Telenor, OJ L 40, 9.2.2001, p. 1, points 330-331, andCase IV/M.1681 — Akzo Nobel/Hoechst Roussel Vet, point 64.76 Case IV/M.1630 — Air Liquide/BOC, point 219; Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2002/164/EC in Case COMP/M.1853 —EDF/EnBW, OJ L 59, 28.2.2002, p. 1, points 54-64.77 See Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 1999/674/EC in Case M.1221 — Rewe/Meinl, OJ L 274, 23.10.1999, p. 1, points 71-74.78 Case T-22/97, Kesko v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999] ECR II-3775, paragraph 157; Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2002/156/EC inCase M.877 — Boeing/ McD<strong>on</strong>nell Douglas, OJ L 336, 8.12.1997, p. 16, points 105-108.


Val Korah. Case Book2462. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, increased buyer power may be beneficial for competiti<strong>on</strong>. Ifincreased buyer power lowers input costs without restricting downstream competiti<strong>on</strong>or total output, <strong>the</strong>n a proporti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se cost reducti<strong>on</strong>s are likely to be passed <strong>on</strong>toc<strong>on</strong>sumers in <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> lower prices.Analysis required63. In order to assess whe<strong>the</strong>r a merger would significantly impede effective competiti<strong>on</strong>by creating or streng<strong>the</strong>ning buyer power, an analysis <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> competitive c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s inupstream markets and an evaluati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> possible positive and negative effectsdescribed above are <strong>the</strong>refore required.V. COUNTERVAILING BUYER POWER64. The competitive pressure <strong>on</strong> a supplier is not <strong>on</strong>ly exercised by competitors but canalso come from its customers. Even firms with very high market shares may not be ina positi<strong>on</strong>, post-merger, to significantly impede effective competiti<strong>on</strong>, in particular byacting to an appreciable extent independently <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir customers, if <strong>the</strong> latterpossesses countervailing buyer power 79 . Countervailing buyer power in this c<strong>on</strong>textshould be <strong>under</strong>stood as <strong>the</strong> bargaining strength that <strong>the</strong> buyer has vis-à-vis <strong>the</strong> sellerin commercial negotiati<strong>on</strong>s due to its size, its commercial significance to <strong>the</strong> sellerand its ability to switch to alternative suppliers.Ability to counter market power65. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>siders, when relevant, to what extent customers will be in apositi<strong>on</strong> to counter <strong>the</strong> increase in market power that a merger would o<strong>the</strong>rwise belikely to create. One source <strong>of</strong> countervailing buyer power would be if a customercould credibly threaten to resort, within a reas<strong>on</strong>able timeframe, to alternativesources <strong>of</strong> supply should <strong>the</strong> supplier decide to increase prices 80 or to o<strong>the</strong>rwisedeteriorate quality or <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>of</strong> delivery. This would be <strong>the</strong> case if <strong>the</strong> buyercould immediately switch to o<strong>the</strong>r suppliers 81 , credibly threaten to vertically integrate79 See, e.g. Case IV/M.1882 — Pirelli/BICC, points 73-80.80 See, e.g. Case IV/M.1245 — Valeo/ITT Industries, point 26.81 Even a small number <strong>of</strong> customers may not have sufficient buyer power if <strong>the</strong>y are to a large extent ‘locked in’because <strong>of</strong> high switching costs (see Case COMP/M.2187 — CVC/Lenzing, point 223).


Val Korah. Case Book25into <strong>the</strong> upstream market or to sp<strong>on</strong>sor upstream expansi<strong>on</strong> or entry 82 for instance bypersuading a potential entrant to enter by committing to placing large orders with thiscompany. It is more likely that large and sophisticated customers will possess thiskind <strong>of</strong> countervailing buyer power than smaller firms in a fragmented industry 83 . Abuyer may also exercise countervailing buying power by refusing to buy o<strong>the</strong>rproducts produced by <strong>the</strong> supplier or, particularly in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> durable goods,delaying purchases.Incentives to exercise buying power66. In some cases, it may be important to pay particular attenti<strong>on</strong> to <strong>the</strong> incentives <strong>of</strong>buyers to utilise <strong>the</strong>ir buyer power 84 . For example, a downstream firm may not wish tomake an investment in sp<strong>on</strong>soring new entry if <strong>the</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> such entry in terms <strong>of</strong>lower input costs could also be reaped by its competitors.Countervailing power beneficial, <strong>on</strong>ly if most customers protected after merger67. Countervailing buyer power cannot be found to sufficiently <strong>of</strong>f-set potential adverseeffects <strong>of</strong> a merger if it <strong>on</strong>ly ensures that a particular segment <strong>of</strong> customers 85 , withparticular bargaining strength, is shielded from significantly higher prices ordeteriorated c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s after <strong>the</strong> merger 86 . Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, it is not sufficient that buyerpower exists prior to <strong>the</strong> merger; it must also exist and remain effective following <strong>the</strong>merger. This is because a merger <strong>of</strong> two suppliers may reduce buyer power if it<strong>the</strong>reby removes a credible alternative.VI. ENTRYLittle anti-competitive risk if entry easy82 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 1999/641/EC in Case COMP/M.1225 — Enso/Stora, OJ L 254, 29.9.1999, p. 9, points 89-91.83 It may also be appropriate to compare <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> existing <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> customer side with <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>supply side (Case COMP/JV 55 — Hutchis<strong>on</strong>/RCPM/ECT, point 119, and Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 1999/641/EC in CaseCOMP/M.1225 — Enso/Stora, OJ L 254, 29.9.1999, p. 9, point 97).84 Case COMP/JV 55 — Hutchis<strong>on</strong>/RCPM/ECT, points 129-130.85 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2002/156/EC in Case COMP/M.2097 — SCA/Metsä Tissue, OJ L 57, 27.2.2002, point 88.Price discriminati<strong>on</strong> between different categories <strong>of</strong> customers may be relevant in some cases in <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>text <strong>of</strong> marketdefiniti<strong>on</strong> (See <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>'s notice <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> definiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> relevant market, cited above, at paragraph 43).86 Accordingly, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> may assess whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> various purchasers will hold countervailing buyer power, see,e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 1999/641/EC in Case COMP/M.1225 — Enso/Stora, OJ L 254, 29.9.1999, p. 9, points 84-97.


Val Korah. Case Book2668. When entering a market is sufficiently easy, a merger is unlikely to pose anysignificant anti-competitive risk. Therefore, entry analysis c<strong>on</strong>stitutes an importantelement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> overall competitive <strong>assessment</strong>. For entry to be c<strong>on</strong>sidered a sufficientcompetitive c<strong>on</strong>straint <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging parties, it must be shown to be likely, timelyand sufficient to deter or defeat any potential anti-competitive effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger.Likelihood <strong>of</strong> entry69. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> examines whe<strong>the</strong>r entry is likely or whe<strong>the</strong>r potential entry is likelyto c<strong>on</strong>strain <strong>the</strong> behaviour <strong>of</strong> incumbents post-merger. For entry to be likely, it mustbe sufficiently pr<strong>of</strong>itable taking into account <strong>the</strong> price effects <strong>of</strong> injecting additi<strong>on</strong>aloutput into <strong>the</strong> market and <strong>the</strong> potential resp<strong>on</strong>ses <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> incumbents. Entry is thusless likely if it would <strong>on</strong>ly be ec<strong>on</strong>omically viable <strong>on</strong> a large scale, <strong>the</strong>reby resultingin significantly depressed price levels. And entry is likely to be more difficult if <strong>the</strong>incumbents are able to protect <strong>the</strong>ir market shares by <strong>of</strong>fering l<strong>on</strong>g-term c<strong>on</strong>tracts orgiving targeted pre-emptive price reducti<strong>on</strong>s to those customers that <strong>the</strong> entrant istrying to acquire. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, high risk and costs <strong>of</strong> failed entry may make entry lesslikely. The costs <strong>of</strong> failed entry will be higher; <strong>the</strong> higher is <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> sunk costassociated with entry 87 .Entry barriers70. Potential entrants may encounter barriers to entry which determine entry risks andcosts and thus have an impact <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> entry. Barriers to entry arespecific features <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market, which give incumbent firms advantages over potentialcompetitors. When entry barriers are low, <strong>the</strong> merging parties are more likely to bec<strong>on</strong>strained by entry. C<strong>on</strong>versely, when entry barriers are high, price increases by <strong>the</strong>merging firms would not be significantly c<strong>on</strong>strained by entry. Historical examples <strong>of</strong>entry and exit in <strong>the</strong> industry may provide useful informati<strong>on</strong> about <strong>the</strong> size <strong>of</strong> entrybarriers.Examples <strong>of</strong> entry barriers71. Barriers to entry can take various forms:87 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 97/610/EC in Case IV/M.774 — Saint-Gobain/Wacker-Chemie/NOM, OJ L 247, 10.9.1997, p.1, point 184.


Val Korah. Case Book27(a)(b)(c)Legal advantages encompass situati<strong>on</strong>s where regulatory barriers limit <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong>market participants by, for example, restricting <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> licences 88 . They alsocover tariff and n<strong>on</strong>-tariff trade barriers 89 .The incumbents may also enjoy technical advantages, such as preferential access toessential facilities, natural resources 90 , innovati<strong>on</strong> and R & D 91 , or intellectualproperty rights 92 , which make it difficult for any firm to compete successfully. Forinstance, in certain industries, it might be difficult to obtain essential input materials,or patents might protect products or processes. O<strong>the</strong>r factors such as ec<strong>on</strong>omies <strong>of</strong>scale and scope, distributi<strong>on</strong> and sales networks 93 , access to important technologies,may also c<strong>on</strong>stitute barriers to entry.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, barriers to entry may also exist because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> established positi<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>incumbent firms <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> market. In particular, it may be difficult to enter a particularindustry because experience or reputati<strong>on</strong> is necessary to compete effectively, both <strong>of</strong>which may be difficult to obtain as an entrant. Factors such as c<strong>on</strong>sumer loyalty to aparticular brand 94 , <strong>the</strong> closeness <strong>of</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships between suppliers and customers, <strong>the</strong>importance <strong>of</strong> promoti<strong>on</strong> or advertising, or o<strong>the</strong>r advantages relating to reputati<strong>on</strong> 95will be taken into account in this c<strong>on</strong>text. Barriers to entry also encompass situati<strong>on</strong>swhere <strong>the</strong> incumbents have already committed to building large excess capacity 96 , orwhere <strong>the</strong> costs faced by customers in switching to a new supplier may inhibit entry.Market evoluti<strong>on</strong>Slow growth, minimum efficient scale large in relati<strong>on</strong> to market, network effects88 Case IV/M.1430 — Vodaf<strong>on</strong>e/Airtouch, point 27; Case IV/M.2016 — France Télécom/Orange, point 33.89 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2002/174/EC in Case COMP/M.1693 — Alcoa/Reynolds, OJ L 58, 28.2.2002, point 87.90 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 95/335/EC in Case IV/M.754 — Anglo American Corp./L<strong>on</strong>rho, OJ L 149, 20.5.1998, p. 21,points 118-119.91 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 97/610/EC in Case IV/M.774 — Saint-Gobain/Wacker-Chemie/NOM, OJ L 247, 10.9.1997, p.1, points 184-187.92 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 94/811/EC in Case IV/M.269 — Shell/M<strong>on</strong>tecatini, OJ L 332, 22.12.1994, p. 48, point 32.93 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 98/327/EC in Case IV/M.833 — The Coca-Cola Company/Carlsberg A/S, OJ L 145, 15.5.1998,p. 41, point 74.94 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 98/327/EC in Case IV/M.833 — The Coca-Cola Company/Carlsberg A/S, OJ L 145, 15.5.1998,p. 41, points 72-73.95 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2002/156/EC in Case COMP/M.2097 — SCA/Metsä Tissue, OJ L 57, 27.2.2002, p. 1, points83-84.96 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2001/432/EC in Case IV/M.1813 — Industri Kapital Nordkem/Dyno, OJ L 154, 9.6.2001, p. 41,point 100.


Val Korah. Case Book2872. The expected evoluti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market should be taken into account when assessingwhe<strong>the</strong>r or not entry would be pr<strong>of</strong>itable. Entry is more likely to be pr<strong>of</strong>itable in amarket that is expected to experience high growth in <strong>the</strong> future 97 than in a market thatis mature or expected to decline 98 . Scale ec<strong>on</strong>omies or network effects may makeentry unpr<strong>of</strong>itable unless <strong>the</strong> entrant can obtain a sufficiently large market share 99 .Producti<strong>on</strong> facilities from o<strong>the</strong>r markets73. Entry is particularly likely if suppliers in o<strong>the</strong>r markets already possess producti<strong>on</strong>facilities that could be used to enter <strong>the</strong> market in questi<strong>on</strong>, thus reducing <strong>the</strong> sunkcosts <strong>of</strong> entry. The smaller <strong>the</strong> difference in pr<strong>of</strong>itability between entry and n<strong>on</strong>-entryprior to <strong>the</strong> merger, <strong>the</strong> more likely such a reallocati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> producti<strong>on</strong> facilities.Timeliness74. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> examines whe<strong>the</strong>r entry would be sufficiently swift and sustained todeter or defeat <strong>the</strong> exercise <strong>of</strong> market power. What c<strong>on</strong>stitutes an appropriate timeperiod depends <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> characteristics and dynamics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market, as well as <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>specific capabilities <strong>of</strong> potential entrants 100 . However, entry is normally <strong>on</strong>lyc<strong>on</strong>sidered timely if it occurs within two years.Sufficiency75. Entry must be <strong>of</strong> sufficient scope and magnitude to deter or defeat <strong>the</strong> anticompetitiveeffects <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger 101 . Small-scale entry, for instance, into some market‘niche’, may not be c<strong>on</strong>sidered sufficient.VII. EFFICIENCIESFactors relevant to overall <strong>assessment</strong>76. Corporate reorganisati<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> <strong>mergers</strong> may be in line with <strong>the</strong> requirements<strong>of</strong> dynamic competiti<strong>on</strong> and are capable <strong>of</strong> increasing <strong>the</strong> competitiveness <strong>of</strong> industry,97 See, e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 98/475/EC in Case IV/M.986 — Agfa-Gevaert/Dup<strong>on</strong>t, OJ L 211, 29.7.1998, p. 22,points 84-85.98 Case T-102/96, Gencor v Commissi<strong>on</strong>, [1999] ECR II-753, paragraph 237.99 See, e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2000/718/EC in Case IV/M.1578 — Sanitec/Sphinx, OJ L 294, 22.11.2000, p. 1, point114.100 See, e.g. Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2002/174/EC in Case COMP/M.1693 — Alcoa/Reynolds, L 58, 28.2.2002, points 31-32, 38.101 Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 91/535/EEC in Case IV/M.68 — Tetra Pak/Alfa Laval, OJ L 290, 22.10.1991, p. 35, point 3.4.


Val Korah. Case Book29<strong>the</strong>reby improving <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>of</strong> growth and raising <strong>the</strong> standard <strong>of</strong> living in <strong>the</strong>Community 102 . It is possible that efficiencies brought about by a merger counteract<strong>the</strong> effects <strong>on</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> and in particular <strong>the</strong> potential harm to c<strong>on</strong>sumers that itmight o<strong>the</strong>rwise have 103 . In order to assess whe<strong>the</strong>r a merger would significantlyimpede effective competiti<strong>on</strong>, in particular through <strong>the</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> or <strong>the</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>ning<strong>of</strong> a dominant positi<strong>on</strong>, within <strong>the</strong> meaning <strong>of</strong> Article 2(2) and (3) <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> MergerRegulati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> performs an overall competitive appraisal <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger.In making this appraisal, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> takes into account <strong>the</strong> factors menti<strong>on</strong>ed inArticle 2(1), including <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> technical and ec<strong>on</strong>omic progress providedthat it is to <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumers' advantage and does not form an obstacle to competiti<strong>on</strong> 104 .Substantial efficiencies – balance adverse effects77. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>siders any substantiated efficiency claim in <strong>the</strong> overall<strong>assessment</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger. It may decide that, as a c<strong>on</strong>sequence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> efficiencies that<strong>the</strong> merger brings about, <strong>the</strong>re are no grounds for declaring <strong>the</strong> merger incompatiblewith <strong>the</strong> comm<strong>on</strong> market pursuant to Article 2(3) <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong>. This willbe <strong>the</strong> case when <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> is in a positi<strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>clude <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>of</strong> sufficientevidence that <strong>the</strong> efficiencies generated by <strong>the</strong> merger are likely to enhance <strong>the</strong> abilityand incentive <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merged entity to act pro-competitively for <strong>the</strong> benefit <strong>of</strong>c<strong>on</strong>sumers, <strong>the</strong>reby counteracting <strong>the</strong> adverse effects <strong>on</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> which <strong>the</strong>merger might o<strong>the</strong>rwise have.C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s: benefit c<strong>on</strong>sumers, merger specific and verifiable78. For <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> to take account <strong>of</strong> efficiency claims in its <strong>assessment</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>merger and be in a positi<strong>on</strong> to reach <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> that as a c<strong>on</strong>sequence <strong>of</strong>efficiencies <strong>the</strong>re are no grounds for declaring <strong>the</strong> merger to be incompatible with <strong>the</strong>comm<strong>on</strong> market, <strong>the</strong> efficiencies have to benefit c<strong>on</strong>sumers, be merger-specific and beverifiable. These c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s are cumulative.Benefit to c<strong>on</strong>sumers102 See Recital 4 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong>.103 See Recital 29 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong>.104 Cf. Article 2(1)(b) <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Merger Regulati<strong>on</strong>.


Val Korah. Case Book3079. The relevant benchmark in assessing efficiency claims is that c<strong>on</strong>sumers 105 will not beworse <strong>of</strong>f as a result <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger. For that purpose, efficiencies should be substantialand timely, and should, in principle, benefit c<strong>on</strong>sumers in those relevant marketswhere it is o<strong>the</strong>rwise likely that competiti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerns would occur.Cost savings especially in marginal costs- balance benefits and detriments to c<strong>on</strong>sumers80. Mergers may bring about various types <strong>of</strong> efficiency gains that can lead to lowerprices or o<strong>the</strong>r benefits to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. For example, cost savings in producti<strong>on</strong> ordistributi<strong>on</strong> may give <strong>the</strong> merged entity <strong>the</strong> ability and incentive to charge lowerprices following <strong>the</strong> merger. In line with <strong>the</strong> need to ascertain whe<strong>the</strong>r efficiencies willlead to a net benefit to c<strong>on</strong>sumers, cost efficiencies that lead to reducti<strong>on</strong>s in variableor marginal costs 106 are more likely to be relevant to <strong>the</strong> <strong>assessment</strong> <strong>of</strong> efficienciesthan reducti<strong>on</strong>s in fixed costs; <strong>the</strong> former are, in principle, more likely to result inlower prices for c<strong>on</strong>sumers 107 . Cost reducti<strong>on</strong>s, which merely result from anticompetitivereducti<strong>on</strong>s in output, cannot be c<strong>on</strong>sidered as efficiencies benefitingc<strong>on</strong>sumers.New or improved products81. C<strong>on</strong>sumers may also benefit from new or improved products or services, for instanceresulting from efficiency gains in <strong>the</strong> sphere <strong>of</strong> R & D and innovati<strong>on</strong>. A joint venturecompany set up in order to develop a new product may bring about <strong>the</strong> type <strong>of</strong>efficiencies that <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> can take into account.Co-ordinated effects82. In <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>text <strong>of</strong> coordinated effects, efficiencies may increase <strong>the</strong> merged entity'sincentive to increase producti<strong>on</strong> and reduce prices, and <strong>the</strong>reby reduce its incentive tocoordinate its market behaviour with o<strong>the</strong>r firms in <strong>the</strong> market. Efficiencies may<strong>the</strong>refore lead to a lower risk <strong>of</strong> coordinated effects in <strong>the</strong> relevant market.105 Pursuant to Article 2(1)(b), <strong>the</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cept <strong>of</strong> ‘c<strong>on</strong>sumers’ encompasses intermediate and ultimate c<strong>on</strong>sumers, i.e. users<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> products covered by <strong>the</strong> merger. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, c<strong>on</strong>sumers within <strong>the</strong> meaning <strong>of</strong> this provisi<strong>on</strong> include <strong>the</strong>customers, potential and/or actual, <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> parties to <strong>the</strong> merger.106 Variable costs should be viewed as those costs that vary with <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> producti<strong>on</strong> or sales over <strong>the</strong> relevant timeperiod. Marginal costs are those costs associated with expanding producti<strong>on</strong> or sales at <strong>the</strong> margin.107 Generally, fixed cost savings are not given such weight as <strong>the</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship between fixed costs and c<strong>on</strong>sumer pricesis normally less direct, at least in <strong>the</strong> short run.


Val Korah. Case Book31Less weight given to delayed effects83. In general, <strong>the</strong> later <strong>the</strong> efficiencies are expected to materialise in <strong>the</strong> future, <strong>the</strong> lessweight <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> can assign to <strong>the</strong>m. This implies that, in order to bec<strong>on</strong>sidered as a counteracting factor, <strong>the</strong> efficiencies must be timely.Need to pass benefit <strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>sumers84. The incentive <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merged entity to pass efficiency gains <strong>on</strong> toc<strong>on</strong>sumers is <strong>of</strong>ten related to <strong>the</strong> existence <strong>of</strong> competitive pressure from <strong>the</strong> remainingfirms in <strong>the</strong> market and from potential entry. The greater <strong>the</strong> possible negative effects<strong>on</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>the</strong> more <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> has to be sure that <strong>the</strong> claimed efficienciesare substantial, likely to be realised, and to be passed <strong>on</strong>, to a sufficient degree, to <strong>the</strong>c<strong>on</strong>sumer. It is highly unlikely that a merger leading to a market positi<strong>on</strong>approaching that <strong>of</strong> a m<strong>on</strong>opoly, or leading to a similar level <strong>of</strong> market power, can bedeclared compatible with <strong>the</strong> comm<strong>on</strong> market <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> ground that efficiency gainswould be sufficient to counteract its potential anti-competitive effects.Merger specificityBurden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong>85. Efficiencies are relevant to <strong>the</strong> competitive <strong>assessment</strong> when <strong>the</strong>y are a directc<strong>on</strong>sequence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> notified merger and cannot be achieved to a similar extent by lessanticompetitive alternatives. In <strong>the</strong>se circumstances, <strong>the</strong> efficiencies are deemed to becaused by <strong>the</strong> merger and thus, merger-specific 108 . It is for <strong>the</strong> merging parties toprovide in due time all <strong>the</strong> relevant informati<strong>on</strong> necessary to dem<strong>on</strong>strate that <strong>the</strong>reare no less anticompetitive, realistic and attainable alternatives <strong>of</strong> a n<strong>on</strong>c<strong>on</strong>centrativenature (e.g. a licensing agreement, or a cooperative joint venture) or <strong>of</strong>a c<strong>on</strong>centrative nature (e.g. a c<strong>on</strong>centrative joint venture, or a differently structuredmerger) than <strong>the</strong> notified merger which preserve <strong>the</strong> claimed efficiencies. TheCommissi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly c<strong>on</strong>siders alternatives that are reas<strong>on</strong>ably practical in <strong>the</strong> businesssituati<strong>on</strong> faced by <strong>the</strong> merging parties having regard to established business practicesin <strong>the</strong> industry c<strong>on</strong>cerned.108 In line with <strong>the</strong> general principle set out in paragraph 9 <strong>of</strong> this notice.


Val Korah. Case Book32VerifiabilityQuantify if reas<strong>on</strong>ably possible86. Efficiencies have to be verifiable such that <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> can be reas<strong>on</strong>ably certainthat <strong>the</strong> efficiencies are likely to materialise, and be substantial enough to counteracta merger's potential harm to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. The more precise and c<strong>on</strong>vincing <strong>the</strong>efficiency claims are, <strong>the</strong> better <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> can evaluate <strong>the</strong> claims. Wherereas<strong>on</strong>ably possible, efficiencies and <strong>the</strong> resulting benefit to c<strong>on</strong>sumers should<strong>the</strong>refore be quantified. When <strong>the</strong> necessary data are not available to allow for aprecise quantitative analysis, it must be possible to foresee a clearly identifiablepositive impact <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumers, not a marginal <strong>on</strong>e. In general, <strong>the</strong> l<strong>on</strong>ger <strong>the</strong> start <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> efficiencies is projected into <strong>the</strong> future, <strong>the</strong> less probability <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> maybe able to assign to <strong>the</strong> efficiencies actually being brought about.Burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>on</strong> parties87. Most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> informati<strong>on</strong>, allowing <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> to assess whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> merger willbring about <strong>the</strong> sort <strong>of</strong> efficiencies that would enable it to clear a merger, is solely in<strong>the</strong> possessi<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging parties. It is, <strong>the</strong>refore, incumbent up<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> notifyingparties to provide in due time all <strong>the</strong> relevant informati<strong>on</strong> necessary to dem<strong>on</strong>stratethat <strong>the</strong> claimed efficiencies are merger-specific and likely to be realised. Similarly, itis for <strong>the</strong> notifying parties to show to what extent <strong>the</strong> efficiencies are likely tocounteract any adverse effects <strong>on</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> that might o<strong>the</strong>rwise result from <strong>the</strong>merger, and <strong>the</strong>refore benefit c<strong>on</strong>sumers.Evidence88. Evidence relevant to <strong>the</strong> <strong>assessment</strong> <strong>of</strong> efficiency claims includes, in particular,internal documents that were used by <strong>the</strong> management to decide <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger,statements from <strong>the</strong> management to <strong>the</strong> owners and financial markets about <strong>the</strong>expected efficiencies, historical examples <strong>of</strong> efficiencies and c<strong>on</strong>sumer benefit, andpre-merger external experts' studies <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> type and size <strong>of</strong> efficiency gains, and <strong>on</strong><strong>the</strong> extent to which c<strong>on</strong>sumers are likely to benefit.VIII. FAILING FIRMCausati<strong>on</strong>


Val Korah. Case Book3389. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> may decide that an o<strong>the</strong>rwise problematic merger is never<strong>the</strong>lesscompatible with <strong>the</strong> comm<strong>on</strong> market if <strong>on</strong>e <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merging parties is a failing firm.The basic requirement is that <strong>the</strong> deteriorati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> competitive structure thatfollows <strong>the</strong> merger cannot be said to be caused by <strong>the</strong> merger 109 . This will arise where<strong>the</strong> competitive structure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market would deteriorate to at least <strong>the</strong> same extent in<strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger 110 .Three criteria90. The Commissi<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>siders <strong>the</strong> following three criteria to be especially relevant for<strong>the</strong> applicati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> a ‘failing firm defence’. First, <strong>the</strong> allegedly failing firm would in <strong>the</strong>near future be forced out <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market because <strong>of</strong> financial difficulties if not takenover by ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>under</strong>taking. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, <strong>the</strong>re is no less anti-competitive alternativepurchase than <strong>the</strong> notified merger. Third, in <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> a merger, <strong>the</strong> assets <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>failing firm would inevitably exit <strong>the</strong> market 111 .Burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong>91. It is for <strong>the</strong> notifying parties to provide in due time all <strong>the</strong> relevant informati<strong>on</strong>necessary to dem<strong>on</strong>strate that <strong>the</strong> deteriorati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> competitive structure thatfollows <strong>the</strong> merger is not caused by <strong>the</strong> merger.Notes and questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> Horiz<strong>on</strong>tal merger guidelines1. (Points 2-4). It was widely though that <strong>the</strong> criteria developed by <strong>the</strong> CFI inAirtours (CB p.631) and later approved by <strong>the</strong> ECJ would not coverunilateral effects. Do you agree?2. (Point 3). Is an effect <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> same as an effect<strong>on</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> in <strong>the</strong> market?3. (Point 7) Note that <strong>the</strong> courts have left a margin <strong>of</strong> appreciati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong>complex ec<strong>on</strong>omic questi<strong>on</strong>s to <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> as <strong>the</strong> instituti<strong>on</strong>resp<strong>on</strong>sible for <strong>the</strong> orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> policy. What effect does thishave <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> status <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> guidelines? See IMPALA para. 69.109 Joined Cases C-68/94 and C-30/95, Kali and Salz, paragraph 110.110 Joined Cases C-68/94 and C-30/95, Kali and Salz, paragraph 114. See also Commissi<strong>on</strong> Decisi<strong>on</strong> 2002/365/EC inCase COMP/M.2314 — BASF/Pantochim/Eurodiol, OJ L 132, 17.5.2002, p. 45, points 157-160. This requirement islinked to <strong>the</strong> general principle set out in paragraph 9 <strong>of</strong> this notice.111 The inevitability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> assets <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> failing firm leaving <strong>the</strong> market in questi<strong>on</strong> may, in particular in a case <strong>of</strong> mergerto m<strong>on</strong>opoly, <strong>under</strong>lie a finding that <strong>the</strong> market share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> failing firm would in any event accrue to <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r mergingparty. See Joined Cases C-68/94 and C-30/95, Kali and Salz, paragraphs 115-116.


Val Korah. Case Book344. (Point 7). Note that <strong>the</strong>re is no presumpti<strong>on</strong> that a particular mergerbenefits c<strong>on</strong>sumers (IMPALA* Para *)5. (Point 9). The counterfactual is <strong>the</strong> same as has been used for Articles 81and 82 since <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>’s guidelines <strong>on</strong> technology transfer, OJ 2004,C101/2 and <strong>the</strong> notice <strong>on</strong> Article 81(3), OJ 2004, C101/97. Before <strong>the</strong>n, <strong>the</strong>Commissi<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong>ten compared <strong>the</strong> current positi<strong>on</strong> with what would haveoccurred with <strong>the</strong> transacti<strong>on</strong> but without <strong>the</strong> restricti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> c<strong>on</strong>duct. Whichapproach to <strong>the</strong> counterfactual makes better ec<strong>on</strong>omic sense?6. (Point 10). Does <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> define markets merely because <strong>the</strong> ECJheld in C<strong>on</strong>tinental Can that it should do so before finding a dominantpositi<strong>on</strong>, or does it to so for reas<strong>on</strong>s <strong>of</strong> policy? Would it be better toanalyse than define <strong>the</strong> market. Why?7. (Points 12 & 89-91). Note that it is not easy to establish <strong>the</strong> failing firmdefence. It must be shown not <strong>on</strong>ly that <strong>the</strong> firm would have left <strong>the</strong>market had <strong>the</strong> merger not taken place, but also that its assets could nothave been acquired by ano<strong>the</strong>r firm which would have taken its place.8. (Point 13). Is <strong>the</strong> treatment <strong>of</strong> Article 82 by <strong>the</strong> ECJ as flexible as mergerc<strong>on</strong>trol?9. (Point 15). Is it easy to ascertain post-merger market shares in advance <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> merger? Why is market share important? What is <strong>the</strong> problem <strong>of</strong> usingmarket shares when <strong>the</strong>y are volatile?10. (Point 15). Should <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> merely add <strong>the</strong> former market shares?In a c<strong>on</strong>centrated industry, would you expect buyers to shift from <strong>the</strong>merging firms in order to ensure a sec<strong>on</strong>d source <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> product?11. (Point 17). Do you c<strong>on</strong>sider 50% a very large market share? Note that <strong>the</strong>Agencies in <strong>the</strong> US do not c<strong>on</strong>sider m<strong>on</strong>opolisati<strong>on</strong> when <strong>the</strong> post marketshare is below 70%. Nor is an attempt to m<strong>on</strong>opolise <strong>of</strong>ten found below50%.12. (Point 18). At what level is dominance presumed <strong>under</strong> article 82? Is <strong>the</strong>presumpti<strong>on</strong> rebuttable? See AKZO (CB 159 para. 59).13. (Points 16 & 19). What is <strong>the</strong> minimum number <strong>of</strong> firms in a market withan HHI <strong>of</strong> at least 25%? Is this a significant safe harbour?14. (Points 17-21). What is <strong>the</strong> minimum number <strong>of</strong> firms in a market with anHHI <strong>of</strong> 2000?15. (Point 20 (e)). What are facilitating devices? (See Case book 364).C<strong>on</strong>sider agreements to exchange informati<strong>on</strong> about prices or quantitiesbought or sold, announcement <strong>of</strong> prices well in advance. Would you bec<strong>on</strong>cerned if <strong>the</strong> markets were not c<strong>on</strong>centrated: would <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>?


Val Korah. Case Book3516. (Point 22 (a)). Did <strong>the</strong> former merger regulati<strong>on</strong> cover unilateral effects?C<strong>on</strong>vince me! They were not covered by <strong>the</strong> formulati<strong>on</strong> in Airtours para62. Was para 62 exhaustive?17. (Point 25). Note <strong>the</strong> uncertainty created by words like ‘generally,’‘appreciably,’ ‘important,’ ‘may’. There are more such qualificati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>of</strong>uncertain ambit in <strong>the</strong> guidance <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>’s priorities <strong>under</strong>Article 82.18. (Point 31). Note <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> switching costs as well as <strong>the</strong> paucity <strong>of</strong>suppliers.19. (Points 36 & 38).Note <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> incentives as well as <strong>of</strong> rivals’capacity to increase producti<strong>on</strong>.20. (Points 39- 56). See Casebook 618 et seq. & compare Airtours (Case bookPara 631).21. (Point 41). Would <strong>the</strong>se criteria be easy to apply <strong>under</strong> Article 82? It isthought unlikely that much use will be made <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger cases <strong>on</strong> jointdominant positi<strong>on</strong>s when applying article 82.22. (Points 47-57). These are sometimes called ‘facilitating devices’. See Casebook, 364.23. (Points 59, 69 & 73). Why are sunk costs important?24. (Points 62 & 84). Most ec<strong>on</strong>omists favour a total welfare test. Should <strong>the</strong>Commissi<strong>on</strong> advocate a c<strong>on</strong>sumer welfare test? What is <strong>the</strong> difference?Note how <strong>of</strong>ten <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> refers to c<strong>on</strong>sumer welfare.25. (Point 66). Note <strong>the</strong> relevance not <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>of</strong> buyer power, but also <strong>of</strong>incentives to exercise it. Is <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> becoming more realistic?26. (Point 71(a). Note that some ec<strong>on</strong>omists deny that <strong>the</strong>re are any barriers toentry o<strong>the</strong>r than legal restricti<strong>on</strong>s. Few go so far, but ec<strong>on</strong>omies <strong>of</strong> scalematter <strong>on</strong>ly if <strong>the</strong> minimum efficient scale is large in relati<strong>on</strong> to <strong>the</strong> totalmarket. Why? Should competiti<strong>on</strong> law be c<strong>on</strong>cerned <strong>on</strong>ly with barriersagainst equally efficient firms, or also against smaller firms that payproporti<strong>on</strong>ately more for <strong>the</strong>ir finance etc?27. (Point 71(c).An important first mover advantage may exclude newentrants, but should it be balanced against <strong>the</strong> need to encourage <strong>the</strong> firstentrant?28. (Point 72). For network effects, see <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>’s decisi<strong>on</strong> inMicros<strong>of</strong>t, [2005] CMLR 965, paras 448 - 464. It is not reproduced in thisannex as it covered over 300 pages from <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>’s website.29. (Point 72). Ec<strong>on</strong>omies <strong>of</strong> scale are very important when <strong>the</strong> minimumec<strong>on</strong>omic size is large in relati<strong>on</strong> to <strong>the</strong> market: less important when <strong>the</strong>ycut out <strong>on</strong>ly smaller firms. Why?


Val Korah. Case Book3630. (Points 74 and 75). Note how strict <strong>the</strong> qualificati<strong>on</strong>s are to <strong>the</strong> possibility<strong>of</strong> new entry. Does this reflect a view that <strong>mergers</strong> seldom result in <strong>the</strong>expected efficiencies? Half <strong>the</strong> merger decisi<strong>on</strong>s have related to jointventures. Are <strong>the</strong>se more likely to create efficiencies?31. (Point 76 <strong>on</strong>wards). In <strong>the</strong> earlier merger decisi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>believed that efficiencies would make it difficult for l<strong>on</strong>ger for newcomers to enter <strong>the</strong> market. We spoke <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> “merger <strong>of</strong>fence.” Do youthink this was a sensible attitude to take? Have we still got an efficiency<strong>of</strong>fence? The Commissi<strong>on</strong> still insists <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> being <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong>dominant firm (point 87). Are <strong>the</strong> criteria for appraising a merger to befound in Article 2(1) or 2(2) & (3) <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> merger regulati<strong>on</strong>?32. (Points 77 – 80, 84). Note how narrow <strong>the</strong> efficiency justificati<strong>on</strong> is. Is thisbecause so many <strong>mergers</strong> fail to resu1t in <strong>the</strong> expected benefits? Before<strong>the</strong> merger takes place, how can <strong>the</strong> merging firms establish that <strong>the</strong>efficiencies outweigh <strong>the</strong> anticompetitive effects? Are efficiencies andforeclosure commensurate? Note how <strong>of</strong>ten <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> refers toc<strong>on</strong>sumer benefit and c<strong>on</strong>sumer harm. Is this <strong>the</strong> test <strong>of</strong> foreclosure andefficiencies?33. (Point 80). Why are savings in marginal costs more important than savingsin sunk costs?34. (Point 84). Note that <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> accepts <strong>the</strong> criteri<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumerwelfare and not that <strong>of</strong> total welfare, which many ec<strong>on</strong>omists prefer. It isclear that <strong>the</strong> welfare <strong>of</strong> competitors is not <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong>’s test.35. (Point 85). Is this burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> different from <strong>the</strong> burden <strong>under</strong> article82 or 81(3)? Is it ever possible to discharge it? See Micros<strong>of</strong>t, para 688 inCFI judgment and in Glaxo SmithKline paras 235-236.36. (Point 86). Are dynamic efficiencies likely to be more important than staticefficiencies? Which is easier to establish before <strong>the</strong> event?37. (Point 87). Experts have l<strong>on</strong>g been trying to persuade <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> that<strong>on</strong>ly <strong>the</strong> evidentiary burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> is <strong>on</strong> Domco. Have <strong>the</strong>y succeeded?38. (Point 90). In Kali und Salz (France v Commissi<strong>on</strong> (C-68/94 and 30/95),[1998] ECR I-1375) it was not so much financial difficulties, but <strong>the</strong>exhausti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> mine from which <strong>the</strong> chemicals were obtainable that ledto <strong>the</strong> exit <strong>of</strong> <strong>on</strong>e <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firms.39. (Points 89 – 91) Are <strong>the</strong> three criteria in point 90 sufficiently strict? NBunless <strong>the</strong> merger is c<strong>on</strong>demned, <strong>the</strong> Commissi<strong>on</strong> has no power to imposea remedy. Should it suffice that a divisi<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> a company would be forcedout <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market? Is <strong>the</strong> third criteri<strong>on</strong> stricter than <strong>the</strong> definiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>counterfactual in point 9? Should it be?

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!