11.07.2015 Views

Testing for Speculative Bubbles in Stock Markets A ... - Econometrics

Testing for Speculative Bubbles in Stock Markets A ... - Econometrics

Testing for Speculative Bubbles in Stock Markets A ... - Econometrics

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Test<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>Speculative</strong> <strong>Bubbles</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Stock</strong> <strong>Markets</strong>A Comparison of Alternative MethodsUlrich HommJörg BreitungUniversity of BonnAdenauerallee 24-4253113 BonnGermanye-mail: uhomm@uni-bonn.dephone: +49 (0)228 73 39 25University of BonnAdenauerallee 24-4253113 BonnGermanye-mail: breitung@uni-bonn.dephone: +49 (0)228 73 92 011


AbstractIn this paper we <strong>in</strong>vestigate the power properties of various test <strong>for</strong> rational bubbles.We focus on the case where bubble detection is reduced to test<strong>in</strong>g <strong>for</strong> a changefrom a random walk to an explosive process, where the change po<strong>in</strong>t is unknown.We adapt several test procedures, that were orig<strong>in</strong>ally proposed to test <strong>for</strong> a change<strong>in</strong> persistence. In our simulations a Chow type break test exhibits the highest power.We also compare different estimators <strong>for</strong> the unknown break date and suggest monitor<strong>in</strong>gprocedures <strong>for</strong> detect<strong>in</strong>g speculative bubbles <strong>in</strong> real time. As applications weanalyze the Nasdaq and the Hang Seng <strong>in</strong>dex.KEYWORDS: speculative bubbles, unit-root test, structural breakJEL: G10, C22IntroductionPhenomena of speculative excesses have long been present <strong>in</strong> economic history. Galbraith(1993) starts his account with the famous Tulipomania, which took place <strong>in</strong> the Netherlands<strong>in</strong> the 17th century. More recently, the so called dot.com or IT -bubble came to famedur<strong>in</strong>g the end of the 1990s. Enormous <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> stock prices followed by crashes haveled many researchers to test <strong>for</strong> the presence of speculative bubbles. Among these areShiller (1981) and LeRoy and Porter (1981), who proposed variance bounds tests, West(1987), who designed a two-step test <strong>for</strong> bubbles, and Froot and Obstfeld (1991), whoconsidered <strong>in</strong>tr<strong>in</strong>sic bubbles. Moreover, Cuñado, Gil-Alana, and Gracia (2004) and Kruse(2008) employ methods based on fractionally <strong>in</strong>tegrated models, while Phillips, Wu, andYu (2009) use sequential unit-root tests. This list is by no means complete. Gürkaynak(2008) provides an overview of different empirical tests on rational bubbles. Here, weadopt the theoretical framework of Phillips et al. (2009) and propose several other testprocedures aim<strong>in</strong>g to improve on the test<strong>in</strong>g power. The <strong>for</strong>ward recursive unit-root testof Phillips et al. (2009) is an attempt to overcome the weaknesses of the approach of Dibaand Grossman (1988), who argue aga<strong>in</strong>st the existence of bubbles <strong>in</strong> the S&P 500. Evans(1991) demonstrates that Diba and Grossman’s (1988) tests do not have sufficient powerto effectively detect bubbles that collapse periodically. Phillips et al. (2009) also proposeto use sequences of Dickey-Fuller statistics to estimate the date of the emergence of abubble, i.e. to estimate the date of a regime switch from a random walk to an explosiveprocess.There is a wide literature on tests <strong>for</strong> a change <strong>in</strong> persistence of a time series. For<strong>in</strong>stance, Kim (2000) and Busetti and Taylor (2004) proposed procedures to test thenull that the time series is I(0) throughout the entire sample aga<strong>in</strong>st the alternative of achange from I(0) to I(1), or vice versa. In this paper we study the power properties ofthese tests <strong>in</strong> a different context, the detection of rational bubbles, and compare them to2


the procedure proposed by Phillips et al. (2009). Additionally, two other tests will be<strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the study. One is based on Bhargava (1986), who tested whether a time seriesis I(1) aga<strong>in</strong>st an explosive alternative. Bhargava (1986) did not construct his test as atest <strong>for</strong> a regime switch. However, we will tentatively adapt this test to a regime-switchcontext by apply<strong>in</strong>g it sequentially to different subsamples. The other test is a versionof the classical Chow-test. Somewhat unusual, this test will be applied <strong>in</strong> the context ofunit-root processes. Along with different methods to test <strong>for</strong> the existence of bubbles weconsider alternative methods to identify the start<strong>in</strong>g date of the bubble.When there is only one regime switch <strong>in</strong> the sample, the proposed sequential Chowtestand Busetti and Taylor’s (2004) procedure exhibit the highest power. Moreover, abreakpo<strong>in</strong>t estimator derived from the Chow-test turns out to be most accurate. However,this does no longer hold, if there are multiple regime changes due to bubble crashes. Inthat case it is more appropriate to make a slight change of perspective and conceive thebubble tests as monitor<strong>in</strong>g procedures. Basically all procedures could be redesigned asmonitor<strong>in</strong>g procedures, but here we will focus on the sequential Dickey-Fuller test andpropose a simple CUSUM procedure.This paper is organized as follows. In section 1 we present the basic theory of rationalbubbles. In sections 2 and 3, the above mentioned tests and estimation procedures are<strong>in</strong>troduced. Section 4 presents different models of rational bubbles. We <strong>in</strong>troduce a simplemodel <strong>for</strong> randomly start<strong>in</strong>g bubbles and review Evans’ (1991) periodically collaps<strong>in</strong>gbubbles. These two models are part of our Monte Carlo analysis <strong>in</strong> section 5. In section 6we consider monitor<strong>in</strong>g procedures and analyze their properties. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>in</strong> section 7, thetest and estimation procedures are applied to Nasdaq and Hang Seng <strong>in</strong>dex data. Section8 concludes.1 Rational <strong>Bubbles</strong><strong>Speculative</strong> bubbles <strong>in</strong> stock markets are systematic departures from the fundamentalprice of an asset. Follow<strong>in</strong>g Blanchard and Watson (1982) or Campbell, Lo and MacK<strong>in</strong>lay(1997) the fundamental price of the asset is derived from the present value of all expectedpayouts. The return of the stock is def<strong>in</strong>ed asR t+1 = P t+1 + D t+1P t− 1, (1)where P t denotes the stock price at period t and D t+1 is the the dividend <strong>for</strong> the periodt. Assum<strong>in</strong>g risk neutrality, no arbitrage opportunities and a constant expected return(E [R t ] = R <strong>for</strong> all t), the stock price is obta<strong>in</strong>ed asP t = E t [P t+1 + D t+1 ], (2)1 + R3


where E t [·] denotes the expectation conditional on the <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation at time t. Equation(2) can be solved by <strong>for</strong>ward iteration yield<strong>in</strong>gP ftP ft =∞∑i=11(1 + R) i E t [D t+i ] . (3)is often referred to as the fundamental stock price. Impos<strong>in</strong>g the transversality condition[]lim E 1k→∞ (1 + R) P k t+k = 0 (4)the (unique) solution of the difference equation is P t = P ft , that is, the existence ofthe bubble is ruled out. Equation (3) states that the fundamental price is equal tothe present value of all expected dividend payments. In this simple framework, the onlyfundamentals determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the stock price are expected dividend payments and the <strong>in</strong>terestrate. However, if (4) does not hold, P ft is not the only price process that solves (2).Consider a process {B t } ∞ t=1with the propertyE t [B t+1 ] = (1 + R)B t . (5)It can easily be verified that add<strong>in</strong>g B t to P t will yield another solution to equation (2).In fact, there are <strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>itely many solutions to (2). They take the <strong>for</strong>mP t = P ft + B t , (6)where {B t } ∞ t=1is a process that satisfies equation (4). The last equation decomposes theprice <strong>in</strong>to two components: the fundamental component, P ft , and a part that is commonlyreferred to as the bubble component, B t . If a bubble is present <strong>in</strong> the stock price, equation(5) requires that any rational <strong>in</strong>vestor, who is will<strong>in</strong>g to buy that stock, must expect thebubble to grow at a rate that equals the <strong>in</strong>terest rate R. If this is the case and if B tis strictly positive, this builds the stage <strong>for</strong> speculative <strong>in</strong>vestor behavior: A rational<strong>in</strong>vestor is will<strong>in</strong>g to buy an “overpriced” stock, s<strong>in</strong>ce she believes that through price<strong>in</strong>creases she will be sufficiently compensated <strong>for</strong> the extra payment B t . If the bubblecomponent constitutes a large part of the price, then the expectation that it will <strong>in</strong>creaseat rate R means that <strong>in</strong>vestors expect price <strong>in</strong>creases that are unrelated to changes <strong>in</strong>fundamentals. If enough <strong>in</strong>vestors have this expectation and buy shares, the stock pricewill <strong>in</strong>deed go up and complete a loop of a self-fulfill<strong>in</strong>g prophecy.S<strong>in</strong>ce the fundamental value is not observed, assumptions have to be imposed tocharacterize the time series properties of the fundamental price P ft . A convenient – andnevertheless empirically plausible – assumption is that dividends follow a random walkwith driftD t = µ + D t−1 + u t , (7)where u t is a white noise process. Under this assumption the fundamental price results asP ft= 1 + RR 2 µ + 1 R D t, (8)4


(e.g. Evans 1991). Consequently,if D t follows a random walk with drift, so does P ft . Thisallows us to dist<strong>in</strong>guish the fundamental price from the bubble process that is characterizedby an explosive autoregressive process. Diba and Grossman (1988) argue as follows:In the absence of bubbles observed prices are equal to fundamental prices and are hence<strong>in</strong>tegrated of the same order as dividends (see (3) and (8)). On the other hand, if apositive bubble was present, this would cause the stock price to explode. No matter howoften prices are differenced, the result<strong>in</strong>g series will not be stationary. Thus, if pricesexhibit explosive behavior while dividends are <strong>in</strong>tegrated of order 1, say, this <strong>in</strong>dicatesthe presence of a bubble.2 Test ProceduresConjectur<strong>in</strong>g the presence of a bubble <strong>in</strong> the NASDAQ, figure 4 <strong>in</strong> section 7 suggests thatthe explosive feature of the bubble does not dom<strong>in</strong>ate the price from the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g. It<strong>in</strong>dicates a structural change from a random walk to an explosive process <strong>in</strong> the mid 90sand then another switch back to a random walk around the year 2000.We start with the case of a s<strong>in</strong>gle regime switch, where it assumed that the bubbledoes not crash be<strong>for</strong>e the end of the sample. The test procedures are based on the timevary<strong>in</strong>g AR(1) modely t = ρ t y t−1 + ɛ t , (9)where ε t is a white noise process with E(ε t ) = 0, E(ε t ) 2 = σ 2 and y 0 = c < ∞. To simplifythe exposition we ignore a possible constant <strong>in</strong> the autoregression. If the test is appliedto a series of daily stock prices, the constant is usually very small and <strong>in</strong>significant. Toaccount <strong>for</strong> a possible constant <strong>in</strong> (9), the series may be detrended by runn<strong>in</strong>g a leastsquaresregression on a constant and a l<strong>in</strong>ear time trend. All test statistics presented <strong>in</strong>this section are then computed by us<strong>in</strong>g the residuals of this regression <strong>in</strong>stead of theorig<strong>in</strong>al time series. 1Under the null hypothesis y t follows a random walk <strong>for</strong> all time periods, i.e.,H 0 : ρ t = 1 <strong>for</strong> t = 1, 2, . . . , T. (10)Under the alternative hypothesis the process starts as a random walk but changes to anexplosive process at an unknown time [τ ∗ T ] (where τ ∗ ∈ (0, 1) and [τ ∗ T ] denotes thegreatest <strong>in</strong>teger smaller than or equal to τ ∗ T ):⎧⎨ 1 <strong>for</strong> t = 1, . . . , [τ ∗ T ]H 1 : ρ t =(11)⎩ ρ∗ > 1 <strong>for</strong> t = [τ ∗ T ] + 1, . . . , T.Various statistics have been suggested to test <strong>for</strong> a structural break <strong>in</strong> the autoregressiveparameter. Most of the work focus on a change from a nonstationary regime (i.e. ρ t = 1)1 In that case, Brownian motions are replaced by detrended Brownian motions <strong>in</strong> the limit<strong>in</strong>g distributionof the test statistics (see below).5


to a stationary regime (ρ t < 1) or vice versa. S<strong>in</strong>ce these test statistics can easily adaptedto the situation of a change from a I(1) to an explosive process, we first consider varioustest statistics suggested <strong>in</strong> the literature.a) The Bhargava statisticTo test the null hypothesis of a random walk (ρ t = 1) aga<strong>in</strong>st explosive alternativesρ t = ρ∗ > 1 <strong>for</strong> all t = 1, . . . , T , Bhargava 1986 proposed the locally most powerful<strong>in</strong>variant test statistic∑ TB0 ∗ t=1=(y t − y t−1 ) 2∑ Tt=1 (y t − y 0 ) .2S<strong>in</strong>ce Bhargava’s (1986) alternative does not <strong>in</strong>corporate a structural break we will use amodified version of this test statistic. Lets 2 τ =1T − [τT ]T∑t=[τT ]+1(y t − y t−1 ) 2 .To test <strong>for</strong> a change from I(1) to an explosive process <strong>in</strong> the symmetric <strong>in</strong>terval τ ∈[τ 0 , 1 − τ 0 ], where τ 0 ∈ (0, 0.5), we consider the statisticsupB(τ 0 ) =sup B τ , where B τ =τ∈[τ 0 ,1−τ 0 ]1s 2 τ (T − [τT ]) 2T∑t=[τT ]+1(y t − y [τT ] ) 2 . (12)Essentially, B τ is the <strong>in</strong>verse of the statistic B0 ∗ applied to the subsample {y [τT ] , . . . , y T }and divided by T − [τT ]. The statistic may be motivated as follows. Assume that wewant to <strong>for</strong>ecast the value y T ∗ +h at period T ∗ = [τT ]. S<strong>in</strong>ce it is assumed that the seriesis a random walk up to period T ∗ the <strong>for</strong>ecast results as ŷ T ∗ +h|T ∗ = y T ∗. The Bhargavastatistic is based on the sum of squared <strong>for</strong>ecast errors <strong>for</strong> y T ∗ +1, . . . , y T . If the secondpart of the sample is generated by an explosive process, then the random walk <strong>for</strong>ecastbecomes very poor as h gets large. There<strong>for</strong>e, this test statistic is supposed to have goodpower aga<strong>in</strong>st explosive alternatives.The supremum of the statistics B τ is used to cope with the fact that the breakpo<strong>in</strong>tis unknown. The asymptotic distribution of this test statistic under null hypothesis wasnot derived <strong>in</strong> the literature but easily follows from the cont<strong>in</strong>uous mapp<strong>in</strong>g theorem assupB(τ 0 ) ⇒where ⇒ denotes weak convergence.supτ∈[τ 0 ,1−τ 0 ]{∫1 1−τ(1 − τ) 20}W 2 (r)dr ,b) The Busetti-Taylor statisticBusetti and Taylor (2004) proposed a statistic <strong>for</strong> test<strong>in</strong>g the hypothesis that a timeseries is stationary aga<strong>in</strong>st the alternative that it switches from a stationary to an I(1)6


process at an unknown breakpo<strong>in</strong>t. Here we propose a similar test statistic to test thenull hypothesis (10) aga<strong>in</strong>st the alternative (11): 2supBT (τ 0 ) =sup BT τ , where BT τ =τ∈[τ 0 ,1−τ 0 ]1s 2 0(T − [τT ]) 2T∑t=[τT ]+1(y T − y t−1 ) 2 . (13)Note that BT τ employs the variance estimator s 2 0 based on the entire sample, while theBhargava statistic s 2 τ uses only the observations start<strong>in</strong>g at [τT ]. Another way to illustratethe difference between the two test statistics is to note that the BT statistic is based onthe sum of squared <strong>for</strong>ecast errors of <strong>for</strong>ecast<strong>in</strong>g the f<strong>in</strong>al value y T from the periodsy T ∗ + 1, . . . , y T −1 by us<strong>in</strong>g the null hypothesis that y t is generated by a random walk.There<strong>for</strong>e the BT statistic fixes the target to be <strong>for</strong>ecasted, whereas the Bhargava statisticuses multiple <strong>for</strong>ecast horizons of a fixed <strong>for</strong>ecast <strong>in</strong>terval. Intuitively, one would expectthat the statistic BT τ is more affected by an explosive behavior than B τ . The follow<strong>in</strong>gresult <strong>for</strong> the limit<strong>in</strong>g distribution of supBT can easily be derived,∫ 1}sup BT τ ⇒ sup{(1 − τ) −2 W 2 (1 − r)dr .τ∈[τ 0 ,1−τ 0 ]τ∈[τ 0 ,1−τ 0 ]c) The Kim statisticAnother statistic <strong>for</strong> test<strong>in</strong>g the I(0) null hypothesis aga<strong>in</strong>st a change from I(0) to I(1)was proposed by Kim (2000). We will use a slightly modified version of his test statisticyield<strong>in</strong>g:supK(τ 0 ) =supτ∈[τ 0 ,1−τ 0 ]K τ with K τ = (T − [τT ])−2 ∑ Tt=[τT ]+1 (y t − y [τT ] ) 2τ[τT ] −2 ∑ [τT ]t=1 (y t − y 0 ) 2 . (14)The statistic K τ can be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as the scaled ratio of the sum of squared <strong>for</strong>ecast errors.The prediction is made under the assumption that the time series follows a random walk.y 0 is used to <strong>for</strong>ecast y 1 , . . . , y [τT ] (denom<strong>in</strong>ator) and y [τT ] is the <strong>for</strong>ecast of y [τT ]+1 , . . . , y T .The limit<strong>in</strong>g distribution is obta<strong>in</strong>ed as{ ( ) 2∫ 1τsup K τ ⇒ supW }2 (r − τ)drτ∫ ττ∈[τ 0 ,1−τ 0 ]τ∈[τ 0 ,1−τ 0 ] 1 − τ W .0 2 (r) drd) The Phillips et al. statisticIn the context of (9) to (11), Phillips et al. (2009) suggest to use a sequence of Dickey-Fuller (DF) tests. Let ˆρ τ denote the OLS estimator of ρ and ˆσ ρ,τ the usual estimator <strong>for</strong>the standard deviation of ˆρ τ us<strong>in</strong>g the subsample {y 1 , . . . , y [τT ] }. 3 The <strong>for</strong>ward recursive2 In their work Busetti and Taylor (2004) considered the process y t = β 0 + µ t + ɛ t , where β 0 is aconstant, ɛ t ∼ iid N(0, σ 2 ), and µ t is a process that is subject to a possible switch from I(0) to I(1).They proposed the statistic ϕ(τ) = ˆσ −2 (T − [τT ]) −2 ∑ Tt=[τT ]+1( ∑Tj=t ˆɛ j) 2where ˆσ 2 = 1 T∑ Tt=1 ˆɛ2 t andˆɛ t are the residuals from OLS-regression of y t on <strong>in</strong>tercept. In the bubble test<strong>in</strong>g framework consideredhere, it seems reasonable to replace ˆɛ t by y t − y t−1 , which leads to (13).3 In their paper, Phillips, Wu, and Yu (2009) apply augmented Dickey-Fuller tests and use a constant<strong>in</strong> their regression.7


Dickey-Fuller test of H 0 aga<strong>in</strong>st H 1 is given bysupDF (τ 0 ) =sup DF τ with DF τ = ˆρ τ − 1. (15)τ 0 ≤τ≤1ˆσ ρτNote that the DF statistic is computed <strong>for</strong> the asymmetric <strong>in</strong>terval [τ 0 , 1]. In simulationexperiments τ 0 will be set to 0.2, <strong>in</strong> order to start with a sample fraction of reasonablesize. The limit<strong>in</strong>g distribution derived by Phillips at al. (2009) issup DF τ ⇒τ 0 ≤τ≤1supτ 0 ≤τ≤1∫ τW dW 0√ ∫ .τW 0 2e) A Chow-type unit root statistic <strong>for</strong> a structural breakThe test procedure of Phillips et al. (2009) does not take <strong>in</strong>to account that both underthe null hypothesis given <strong>in</strong> (10) and under the alternative given <strong>in</strong> (11) y t is a randomwalk <strong>for</strong> t = 1, . . . , [τ ∗ T ]. This <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation about the data generat<strong>in</strong>g process can be<strong>in</strong>corporated <strong>in</strong> the test procedure by us<strong>in</strong>g a Chow-test <strong>for</strong> a structural break <strong>in</strong> theautoregressive parameter. Under the assumption that ρ t = 1 <strong>for</strong> t = 1, . . . , [τT ] andρ t − 1 = δ > 0 <strong>for</strong> t = [τT ] + 1, . . . , T , the model can be written as∆y t = δ (y t−1 1 {t>[τT ]} ) + ε t , (16)where 1 {·} is an <strong>in</strong>dicator function that equals one when the statement <strong>in</strong> braces is trueand equals zero otherwise. Correspond<strong>in</strong>gly, the null hypothesis of <strong>in</strong>terest is H 0 : δ = 0which is tested aga<strong>in</strong>st the alternative H 1 : δ > 0. It is easy to see that the regressiont-statistic <strong>for</strong> this null hypothesis isDF C τ =T∑∆y t y t−1t=[τT ]+1˜σ τ√T∑yt−12t=[τT ]+1,where˜σ 2 τ = 1T − 2T∑ (∆y t − ̂δ) 2τ y t−1 1 {t>[τT ]}t=2and ̂δ τ denotes the OLS estimator of δ <strong>in</strong> (16). The Chow-type Dickey-Fuller statistic totest <strong>for</strong> a change from I(1) to explosive <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terval τ ∈ [τ 0 , 1 − τ 0 ] can be written asStraight <strong>for</strong>ward derivation yields:supDF C(τ 0 ) ⇒supDF C =sup DF C τ . (17)τ∈[τ 0 ,1−τ 0 ]1sup[{W 2 (1) − W 2 (τ) − (1 − τ)}]2√τ∈[τ 0 ,1−τ 0 ] ∫ .1W τ 2 (r)dr8


In f<strong>in</strong>ite samples, the critical values <strong>for</strong> both, the supDFC and the supDF statistic,depend on the <strong>in</strong>itial value of the time series, if the series is not detrended. There<strong>for</strong>e,whenever a hypothesis about a time series {y t } T t=0 is tested without detrend<strong>in</strong>g, thesestatistics are applied to the trans<strong>for</strong>med series {ỹ t } T t=0 with ỹ t = y t − y 0 .3 Estimation of the break dateAssume that the time series under consideration, {y t } T t=0, can be described by (9) and (11),where τ ∗ is unknown. First, consider the approach that has been proposed by Phillipset al. (2009). In a simple version, the estimate <strong>for</strong> the start<strong>in</strong>g date of the bubble, ˆτ P ,is given by the smallest value of τ ∈ [τ 0 , 1] <strong>for</strong> which DF τ is larger than the right-tail5% critical value derived from the asymptotic distribution of the standard Dickey-Fullert-statistic. There<strong>for</strong>e, the estimator results as 4ˆτ P = <strong>in</strong>fτ≥τ 0{τ : DF τ > 1.28}. (18)The next estimator <strong>for</strong> a change po<strong>in</strong>t was proposed by Busetti and Taylor (2002). 5It supplements their test <strong>for</strong> the existence of a structural change from I(0) to I(1). Theidea is to maximize the ratio of the sample variances of the first and second subsample.Intuitively, <strong>for</strong> the correct break date, the difference between the variance of the secondsubsample (which is assumed to be I(1) under the alternative) and the first sample (whichis assumed to be I(0)) should be maximal. This idea can be adapted <strong>for</strong> estimat<strong>in</strong>g thedate of a change from an I(1) to an explosive process. The estimator results asˆτ BT = argmax τ∈[˜τ,1−˜τ] Λ(τ), where Λ(τ) =(T − [τT ]) −2 T∑[τT∑][τT ] −2∆yt2t [ τT ]+1∆yt2t=1. (19)F<strong>in</strong>ally, we consider an estimator <strong>for</strong> the break po<strong>in</strong>t that is directly related to the supDFCtest. The estimator is given byˆτ DF C = argmax τ∈[˜τ,1−˜τ] DF C τ , (20)where DF C τ is as <strong>in</strong> equation (17). The idea of this estimator is related to that <strong>in</strong>Leybourne, Kim, Smith and Newbold (2003). These authors consider the case of a changefrom I(0) to I(1) and propose a consistent estimator <strong>for</strong> the unknown break po<strong>in</strong>t. Notethat this estimator also maximizes the likelihood function with respect to the break date.Bai and Perron (1998) have shown that the ML estimator <strong>for</strong> the break date is consistent.4 To achieve consistency the significance level has to go to zero as the sample size goes to <strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>ity. Intheir application Phillips et al. (2009) employ log(log(τT ))/100 as critical values. For a sample size ofT = 400 this roughly corresponds to a 4% significance level. The results of our simulation experimentsrema<strong>in</strong> basically unchanged, if these critical values are used.5 As U. Hassler po<strong>in</strong>ted out, Kim et al. (2002) proposed a very similar estimator with Λ(τ) <strong>in</strong> (19)replaced by [τT ] −1 Λ(τ). In our Monte Carlo analysis we f<strong>in</strong>d no noteworthy difference <strong>in</strong> the per<strong>for</strong>manceof these two estimators. For brevity, we present only the estimator of Busetti and Taylor (2002).9


4 Models <strong>for</strong> rational bubblesThe simplest example of a process that satisfies (5) is the determ<strong>in</strong>istic bubble, given byB t = (1 + R) t B 0 , where B 0 is an <strong>in</strong>itial value. A somewhat more realistic example, <strong>in</strong>which the bubble does not necessarily grow <strong>for</strong>ever, is taken from Blanchard and Watson(1982). The bubble process is given by⎧⎨π −1 (1 + R)B t + µ t+1 , with probability πB t+1 =(21)⎩µ t+1 , with probability 1 − πwhere {µ t } ∞ t=1 is a sequence of iid random variables with zero mean. In each period,the bubble described <strong>in</strong> equation (21) will cont<strong>in</strong>ue, with probability π, or collapse withprobability 1 − π. As long as the bubble does not collapse, the realized return exceedsthe <strong>in</strong>terest rate R as a compensation <strong>for</strong> the risk that the bubble bursts.Not every process that satisfies (4) is consistent with rationality. For <strong>in</strong>stance, giventhat stock prices cannot be negative, negative bubbles can be excluded: Apply<strong>in</strong>g the lawof iterated expectations to (4) yields E t [B t+τ ] = (1 + R) τ B t . If at some time t, B t wasnegative, then, as τ goes to <strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>ity, the expected bubble size would tend towards m<strong>in</strong>us<strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>ity, imply<strong>in</strong>g a negative expected stock price at some future time period. Furthermore,Diba and Grossman (1998) argue that a bubble process cannot start from zero. Assumethat B t = 0 at some time t. Then E t [B t+1 ] = 0, by (4). Assum<strong>in</strong>g nonnegative stockprices, we have B t+1 ≥ 0. Together this implies that B t+1 = 0 almost surely.Although rational bubbles cannot start from zero, they can take a constant positive value<strong>for</strong> some time and start to grow exponentially with some probability π. For <strong>in</strong>stance,consider the follow<strong>in</strong>g randomly start<strong>in</strong>g bubble:⎧⎨B t−1 + RB t−1θπ t , if B t−1 = B 0B t =<strong>for</strong> t = 1, . . . , T, (22)⎩(1 + R)B t−1 , if B t−1 > B 0where B 0 is the <strong>in</strong>itial value of the bubble. R is the <strong>in</strong>terest rate and {θ} T t=1is an exogenousiid Bernoulli process with P rob(θ t = 1) = π = 1 − P rob(θ t = 0), and π ∈ (0, 1]. π is theprobability that the bubble starts to grow exponentially <strong>in</strong> period t+1, under the conditionthat it still is at its <strong>in</strong>itial value, B 0 , <strong>in</strong> period t. A process generated accord<strong>in</strong>g to (22)starts at some strictly positive value B 0 and rema<strong>in</strong>s at that level until the Bernoulliprocess has taken the value 1. At that po<strong>in</strong>t, the process B t makes a jump of size RB 0πand from then on grows at rate R. One can easily verify that such a process satisfiesthe no arbitrage condition <strong>for</strong> rational bubbles, given <strong>in</strong> (5). In our Monte Carlo analysiswe will simulate such a bubble process together with a fundamental price P ft generatedaccord<strong>in</strong>g to (7) and (8). An example of the result<strong>in</strong>g price processes P t = P ft + B t isgiven <strong>in</strong> figure 1 (solid l<strong>in</strong>e), which also depicts the fundamental price (dotted l<strong>in</strong>e). Inthis example the parameters <strong>for</strong> the bubble process are π = 0.05, R = 0.05, and B 0 = 1.Follow<strong>in</strong>g Evans (1991) the dividend process <strong>in</strong> (7) is simulated with drift µ = 0.0373,10


<strong>in</strong>itial value D 0 = 1.3 and identical normally distributed disturbances with mean zero andvariance σ 2 = 0.1574.In his critique of Diba and Grossman’s (1988) test<strong>in</strong>g approach Evans (1991) <strong>for</strong>mulatedhis periodically collaps<strong>in</strong>g bubble:⎧⎨(1 + R)B t u t+1 , if B t ≤ αB t+1 =⎩[δ + π −1 (1 + R)θ t+1 (B t − (1 + R) −1 δ)] u t+1 , otherwise . (23)Here, δ and α are parameters satisfy<strong>in</strong>g 0 < δ < (1+R)α, and {u t } ∞ t=1 is an iid process withu t ≥ 0 and E t [u t+1 ] = 1, <strong>for</strong> all t. {θ t } ∞ t=1 is an iid Bernoulli process, where the probabilitythat θ t = 1 is π and the probability that θ t = 0 is 1 − π, with 0 < π ≤ 1. R is the <strong>in</strong>terestrate. One can easily verify that the bubble process def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> (23) satisfies (5). Lett<strong>in</strong>gthe <strong>in</strong>itial value B 0 = δ, the bubble <strong>in</strong>creases until it exceeds some value α. Thereafter,it is subject to the possibility of collapse with probability (1 − π), <strong>in</strong> which case it willreturn to δu t+1 (i.e. to δ <strong>in</strong> expectation). For our simulations we will follow Evans (1991)and specify u t = exp(ξ t − 1 2 τ 2 ), where ξ t ∼ iid N(0, τ 2 ). The parameter values are set toα = 1, δ = 0.5, τ = 0.05 and R = 0.05. Note that such a periodically collaps<strong>in</strong>g bubblenever crashes to zero. Thus, it does not violate Diba and Grossmans (1988) f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g that abubble cannot restart from zero. Evans (1991) demonstrated that Diba and Grossman’s(1988) tests lack sufficient power to detect periodically collaps<strong>in</strong>g bubbles, even if theprobability of collapse is small. A realization of a periodically collaps<strong>in</strong>g bubble is shown<strong>in</strong> the right panel of figure 2, where π = 0.85. The left panel of figure 2 displays thefundamental price (dotted l<strong>in</strong>e), which is generated as above, and the observed price(solid l<strong>in</strong>e). The observed price is constructed asP t = P ft + 20B t . (24)As <strong>in</strong> Evans (1991), the bubble process is multiplied by a factor of 20. This is to ensurethat the variance of the first difference of the bubble component ∆(20B t ) is large relativeto the variance of first difference of the fundamental price ∆P ft .5 Monte Carlo AnalysisWe start our Monte Carlo analysis with<strong>in</strong> our basic framework <strong>in</strong> (9) – (11). In section 5.1we compute critical values and present the results <strong>for</strong> the power of the tests. Furthermore,we consider price processes that conta<strong>in</strong> explicitly modeled bubbles. We <strong>in</strong>vestigate thepower of the tests to detect randomly start<strong>in</strong>g bubbles (section 5.2) and periodicallycollaps<strong>in</strong>g bubbles (section 5.3). F<strong>in</strong>ally, we evaluate the properties of the break po<strong>in</strong>testimators <strong>in</strong> section 5.4.5.1 <strong>Test<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>for</strong> a Change from I(1) to explosiveWe use Monte Carlo simulation to calculate critical values <strong>for</strong> the test statistics supDF,supB, supBT, supK, and supDFC and we <strong>in</strong>vestigate the power of the perta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g tests to11


detect a change from I(1) to explosive <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ite samples. For the supDF statistic, we startthe <strong>for</strong>ward recursion at a sample fraction of τ 0 = 0.2 (see (15)). For the other statisticswe set τ 0 equal to 0.1 (see (12) – (14) and (17)). To calculate critical values, data isgenerated accord<strong>in</strong>g to equation (9) with ρ t = 1 (<strong>for</strong> all t), an <strong>in</strong>itial value y 0 = 0, andgaussian white noise. 10.000 replications are per<strong>for</strong>med <strong>for</strong> vary<strong>in</strong>g sample sizes amongT = 100, T = 200 and T = 400. We apply the test statistics to the orig<strong>in</strong>al and to thedetrended series, i.e. to the residuals from the regression of y t on a constant and a l<strong>in</strong>eartime trend. The results are reported <strong>in</strong> table 1.To calculate the empirical power of the tests, we generate data accord<strong>in</strong>g to (9) and(11). 2000 replications are per<strong>for</strong>med <strong>for</strong> the sample sizes T = 100, T = 200 and T = 400.We consider vary<strong>in</strong>g break po<strong>in</strong>ts τ ∗ and vary<strong>in</strong>g growth rates ρ. The power of the testsis evaluated at a nom<strong>in</strong>al size of 5%, i.e. a test rejects the null hypothesis when thecorrespond<strong>in</strong>g statistic is greater than the respective 0.95-quantile <strong>in</strong> table 1. The resultsare reported <strong>in</strong> tables 2 and 3.The tests that have the highest power are the supDFC test and the supBT test. Theyper<strong>for</strong>m better than the supDF test <strong>in</strong> all parameter constellations. The power of thesupB test is comparable with that of the supDF test. Only <strong>in</strong> a few cases does the supKtest have substantial power. It is the weakest among the considered tests. The advantageof the supDFC test and the supBT test over the supDF test tends to <strong>in</strong>crease as the breakfraction τ ∗ <strong>in</strong>creases. For <strong>in</strong>stance, when T = 400, ρ = 1.03 and τ ∗ = 0.7 the power of thethree tests is approximately equal, while <strong>for</strong> T = 400, ρ = 1.03 and τ ∗ = 0.9 the supDFtest rejects the null hypothesis <strong>in</strong> only 50% of the cases, whereas the supDFC test andthe supBT test can reject the null <strong>in</strong> more than 75% of the cases.5.2 Randomly Start<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Bubbles</strong>We now <strong>in</strong>vestigate how well the tests can detect randomly start<strong>in</strong>g bubbles. We use themodel presented <strong>in</strong> section 4. That is we simulate the price process as P t = P ft +B t , whereB t is generated as <strong>in</strong> (22) and P ftfollows (7) and (8). The parameters are also specifiedas <strong>in</strong> section 4. S<strong>in</strong>ce the fundamental price follows a random walk with drift, we detrendthe time series be<strong>for</strong>e apply<strong>in</strong>g the tests. The results are given <strong>in</strong> table 4. The null andthe alternative hypothesis are as <strong>in</strong> equations (9) to (11). Rejection of the null is evidence<strong>for</strong> a bubble, s<strong>in</strong>ce dividends follow a random walk and the fundamental price obeys thepresent value model. The nom<strong>in</strong>al size is 5%. The sample sizes are T = 100 and T = 200.For each parameter constellation 2000 replications of the price process P t = P ft + B t areconducted. Cases <strong>in</strong> which a bubble rema<strong>in</strong>s at its <strong>in</strong>itial value <strong>for</strong> more than 90% of itsrealizations are excluded from the experiment.Note that <strong>for</strong> the first row of table 4 we have simulated just the fundamental price.This shows that the tests have correct size.When the sample size equals T = 100, the supDFC test and the supBT test have thehighest rejection frequencies. In most cases they reject the null hypothesis at least 15%12


more often than the supDF test or the supB test. As <strong>in</strong> section 5, the supK test is thetest with the lowest rejection frequencies. When the sample size is T = 200 and B 0 is0.05, 6 the differences between the tests are less pronounced. Still, the supK test shows theweakest per<strong>for</strong>mance among the tests, while the supDFC test and the supBT test havethe highest f<strong>in</strong>ite sample power.An <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g observation is that, when T = 100 and B 0 = 2, some of the tests donot show an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> power, when the probability, that the bubble starts next period,gets higher. This seems odd, s<strong>in</strong>ce the expected time of the bubble start, which is 1 π , isearlier the higher π is. However, the parameter π also has another effect on the bubbleprocess. As can be seen <strong>in</strong> equation (22), there is a jump <strong>in</strong> the bubble process, at thepo<strong>in</strong>t, where it starts to grow explosively. This jump is smaller when π is higher. Forcerta<strong>in</strong> cases the two impacts of π on the bubble process offset each other with regard tothe ability of the tests to detect the bubble. This can be seen <strong>for</strong> the supDF test, thesupK test, and the supB test.Summ<strong>in</strong>g up, the simulation experiments with randomly start<strong>in</strong>g bubbles confirm theresults of section 5.1, that the supDFC test and the supBT test are most powerful amongthe considered tests.5.3 Periodically Collaps<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Bubbles</strong>We now analyze how well the tests are suited to detect Evans’ (1991) periodically collaps<strong>in</strong>gbubbles. The price process P t = P ft + 20B t is generated as described <strong>in</strong> section4. The tests are then applied to the detrended series. As <strong>in</strong> the previous section we takerejection (at the 5% level) of the I(1)-null hypothesis as equivalent to the detection of abubble.Table 5 reports the rejection frequencies of the tests <strong>in</strong> our Monte Carlo experiments.2000 replications of the price process P t have been per<strong>for</strong>med <strong>for</strong> a sample size of T = 100and different values <strong>for</strong> the probability that the bubble lasts (π). Obviously, the f<strong>in</strong>itesample power of the tests decreases when the value of π gets smaller. The more strik<strong>in</strong>gf<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g, however, is that the supDF test is clearly superior to the other tests. For <strong>in</strong>stance,when π = 0.85 the supDF test rejects <strong>in</strong> more than 60% of the cases, while the supK testrejects <strong>in</strong> 33% of the cases and the other tests have rejection frequencies lower than 10%.There is an <strong>in</strong>tuitive explanation of the superiority of the supDF test. In contrastto the other tests, the supDF test is based on subsamples of the <strong>for</strong>m { }P 1 , . . . , P [τT ] .Presumably the DF t-statistic <strong>for</strong> such a subsample is large, when the subsample conta<strong>in</strong>sa long period, <strong>in</strong> which the bubble grows steadily, but does not conta<strong>in</strong> the period afterthe peak. A case <strong>for</strong> which this is clear is provided <strong>in</strong> figure 3. It shows a realizationof the price process P t , when π = 0.85, and the correspond<strong>in</strong>g plot of the DF τ statistic.DF τ is plotted aga<strong>in</strong>st the size of the subsample to which it is applied, which is [τT ].As opposed to the supDF test, the idea beh<strong>in</strong>d the supK test is to oppose the first part6 When B 0 is set to 2, all tests, except the supK tes, have rejection frequencies close to 1 <strong>for</strong> π ≥ 0.05.13


of the sample, { P 1 , . . . , P [τT ]}, to the last part,{P[τT ]+1 , . . . , P T}. But when the bubblecollapses frequently, these two parts have similar properties.The supDFC test, the supBT test, and the supB test essentially build on <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mationfrom the last part of the sample. As the Dickey-Fuller test over the whole sample theyare subject to Evans’ (1991) criticism. When the bubble collapses frequently dur<strong>in</strong>g thelast part of the sample, explosiveness cannot be detected.Thus among the alternative tests, the supDF test has the highest power when appliedto periodically collaps<strong>in</strong>g bubbles. However, <strong>in</strong> applications one might have an obvious<strong>in</strong>dication of where a substantial growth phase of the suspected bubble has ended. If thesubsequent observations are excluded from the sample, the supDFC test and the supBTtest would still be most powerful among the tests considered here.5.4 Estimat<strong>in</strong>g the Break DateIn this section we <strong>in</strong>vestigate the per<strong>for</strong>mance of the estimators from section 3 to datestamp the po<strong>in</strong>t where a time series switches from I(1) to explosive. In the simulationexperiments equations (9) and (11) serve as a model <strong>for</strong> the data generat<strong>in</strong>g process. Theexperiments were conducted <strong>for</strong> different break po<strong>in</strong>ts τ ∗ and <strong>for</strong> sample sizes T = 200 andT = 400. The slope parameter ρ was set to 1.05. For each parameter constellation 2.000replications were per<strong>for</strong>med. Table 6 reports the empirical mean and standard deviation(<strong>in</strong> parentheses) of the break po<strong>in</strong>t estimates. For the estimator proposed by Phillips, Wuand Yu (2009), ˆτ P , we take the 5% right tailed critical value of the standard asymptoticDickey-Fuller distribution (which equals 1.28) as the signal<strong>in</strong>g threshold <strong>for</strong> a change fromI(1) to explosive (cf. (18)). Those realizations of the data generat<strong>in</strong>g process where thethreshold is not reached do not enter the calculations of the mean value and the standarddeviation of the estimates.The results <strong>in</strong> table 6 show that <strong>for</strong> a sample size of T = 200 the estimators do notper<strong>for</strong>m very well: In most cases the mean value of the estimates are far off the true breakpo<strong>in</strong>t and the standard deviations are fairly high. The cases <strong>in</strong> which the mean value ofthe estimates are close to the true break po<strong>in</strong>t seem to be mere co<strong>in</strong>cidence. When thesample size is <strong>in</strong>creased to T = 400 the Chow-style break po<strong>in</strong>t estimator, ˆτ DF C , turnsout to be the most reliable estimator. The mean estimated break fraction is closest to thetrue value and the standard deviation is relatively low. ˆτ P shows a tendency to estimatethe break po<strong>in</strong>t too early. Among all estimators ˆτ P has the largest standard deviation.When T = 400, the standard deviation of ˆτ P is more than twice as large as the standarddeviation of the other estimators. As to ˆτ BT , the mean of the estimated break po<strong>in</strong>ts ismostly about 10% of the sample size higher than the true break po<strong>in</strong>t.Overall, the best results <strong>in</strong> the simulation experiments were achieved by the estimatorˆτ DF C . The use of the estimators ˆτ P and ˆτ BT is questionable <strong>in</strong> samples with no more than400 observations.14


6 Real time monitor<strong>in</strong>gThe test statistics considered <strong>in</strong> the previous sections are designed to detect speculativebubbles with<strong>in</strong> a historical data set. As argued by Chu, St<strong>in</strong>chcombe and White (1996)such test may be highly mislead<strong>in</strong>g when applied to an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g sample. This is dueto the fact that structural break tests are constructed as “one-shot” test procedures, i.e.,the (asymptotic) size of the test is controlled provided that the sample is fixed and thetest procedure is applied only once to the same data set (cf. Chu et al. 1996 and Zeileiset al. 2005). To illustrate the problem <strong>in</strong>volved assume that an <strong>in</strong>vestor is <strong>in</strong>terested tof<strong>in</strong>d out whether the stock price is subject to a speculative bubble. Apply<strong>in</strong>g the testsproposed <strong>in</strong> Section 2 to a sample of the last 100 trad<strong>in</strong>g days (say) he or she is not ableto reject the null hypothesis of no speculative bubbles. If the stock price cont<strong>in</strong>ues to<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the subsequent days the <strong>in</strong>vestor is <strong>in</strong>terested to f<strong>in</strong>d out whether the evidence<strong>for</strong> a speculative bubble has <strong>in</strong>creased. However, repeat<strong>in</strong>g the tests <strong>for</strong> structural breakswhen new observations become available eventually leads to a severe over-rejection of thenull hypothesis due to the multiple application of statistical tests.Another practical problem is that the tests assume a s<strong>in</strong>gle structural break from arandom walk regime to an explosive process. As has been demonstrated <strong>in</strong> our MonteCarlo simulations the tests generally lack power if the bubble bursts with<strong>in</strong> the sample,that is, if there is an additional structural break back to a random walk process. Themonitor<strong>in</strong>g procedure suggested <strong>in</strong> this section is able to sidestep the problems due tomultiple breaks.Assume that, be<strong>for</strong>e the monitor<strong>in</strong>g starts, a tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g sample of n observations isavailable and that the null hypothesis of no structural break holds <strong>for</strong> the tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g sample.Then, <strong>in</strong> each period a new observation n + 1, n + 2, . . . arrives. As we will argue below,it is important to fix <strong>in</strong> advance the maximal length of the monitor<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terval n + 1, n +2, . . . , N = kn as the critical value depends on N. Follow<strong>in</strong>g Chu et al. (1996) we considertwo different statistics (detectors):CUSUM:S t n = ˆσ −1tt∑j=n+1y j − y j−1 = ˆσ −1t (y t − y n ) (t > n)rDF: Z t = ˆv −1/2t (ˆρ t − 1) = DF t/n (t > n)where ˆv t = ˆσ 2 t /( ∑ t−1j=1 y2 j ). ˆρ t denotes the OLS estimate of the autoregressive coefficient andˆσ 2 t is some consistent estimator of the residual variance based on the sample {y 0 , . . . , y t }.Note that Chu et al. (1996) suggest a fluctuation test statistic based on the coefficients ˆρ t .S<strong>in</strong>ce the coefficient ρ t is equal to unity under the null hypothesis, the rDF is essentiallysimilar to the fluctuation statistic advocated by Chu et al. (1996).15


Under the null hypothesis the functional central limit theorem implies as n → ∞1√ nS [λn]n ⇒ W (λ) − W (1) (1 ≤ λ ≤ k)Z [λn]⇒∫ λ/ √ ∫ λW (r)dW (r) W (r) 2 dr00(1 ≤ λ ≤ k),where W (r) is a Brownian motion def<strong>in</strong>ed on the <strong>in</strong>terval r ∈ [0, k]. Our CUSUM monitor<strong>in</strong>gis based on the fact that (see Chu et al. 1996)(lim P √ )|Sn| t > c t t <strong>for</strong> some t ∈ {n + 1, n + 2, . . . , N} ≤ exp(−a 2 /2), (25)n→∞wherec t = √ a 2 + log(t/n)(t > n).For the significance level of 0.05 we obta<strong>in</strong> a 2 = 6.S<strong>in</strong>ce our null hypothesis is one-sided (i.e. we reject the null hypothesis <strong>for</strong> largepositive values of Sn) t and Sn t is distributed symmetrically around zero, a one-sided decisionrule is adopted as follows. The null hypothesis is rejected if S t exceeds the threshold c ∗ tthe first time, that is,reject H 0 if S t n > c ∗ t√t <strong>for</strong> some t > n, (26)where c ∗ t is constructed as c t but us<strong>in</strong>g a value of a that corresponds to the significancelevel α ∗ = 2α. If the orig<strong>in</strong>al significance level is α = 0.05, then we obta<strong>in</strong> a = 4.6.Such a test sequence has the advantage that if the evidence <strong>for</strong> a bubble process issufficiently large the test procedure eventually stops be<strong>for</strong>e the bubble collapses. Accord<strong>in</strong>gly,such a test procedure sidesteps the problem of multiple breaks due to a possibleburst of the bubble.For the second monitor<strong>in</strong>g us<strong>in</strong>g the statistic DF t/n we apply the follow<strong>in</strong>g rule:where the critical is obta<strong>in</strong>ed fromwherereject H 0 if DF t/n > κ N <strong>for</strong> some t > n, (27)P (sup{Q 1 , . . . , Q t } > κ t ) = α, (28)Q t =t∑s=1W s−1 (W s − W s−1 )√t∑Ws−12s=1and W t denotes a random walk with <strong>in</strong>crements W t − W t−1 ∼ N (0, 1). Table 7 presentscritical values <strong>for</strong> various values of N and α. It is important to note that κ N is monotonic<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g and κ N tends to <strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>ity as N → ∞. Thus, the maximal length of the <strong>in</strong>tervalN has to be fixed be<strong>for</strong>e start<strong>in</strong>g the monitor<strong>in</strong>g.16


It is easy to see that the decision rule (27) rejects the null hypothesis of no bubblewith an error probability of maximal α. If we arrive at period N without reject<strong>in</strong>gthe null hypothesis it follows by the decision rule that the implied probability that thewhole sequence of rDF statistics is below the critical level is 1 − α. There<strong>for</strong>e, the errorprobability cannot exceed α. To put it differently, the decision rule is equivalent to a test<strong>in</strong> period N whether the maximum of all DF t/n statistics (n < t ≤ N) exceeds the criticallevel. Hence, by controll<strong>in</strong>g the probability of the f<strong>in</strong>al step of the monitor<strong>in</strong>g procedurewe control the error probability <strong>for</strong> all previous steps at the same time.To <strong>in</strong>vestigate the relative per<strong>for</strong>mance of the tests, a number of Monte Carlo experimentshave been per<strong>for</strong>med. CUSUM denotes the sequential monitor<strong>in</strong>g procedure basedon (25). The monitor<strong>in</strong>g procedure based on the recursive Dickey-Fuller statistics DF t/nis denoted by rDF. The results are presented <strong>in</strong> Table 8. The data generat<strong>in</strong>g process wassimulated as <strong>in</strong> (9) and (11) with slope coefficient ρ = 1.03 under the explosive regime.The total sample size was set to N = 200 and N = 400. The size of the tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g samplewas set to n = 40 and n = 80 respectively. Monitor<strong>in</strong>g boundaries correspond<strong>in</strong>g to a 5%significance level were used. The breakpo<strong>in</strong>t τ ∗ is measured relative to the total samplesize. For each case 5000 replications were per<strong>for</strong>med. We estimated the residual varianceas ˆσ t2 = ˆσ n 2 = (n − 1) ∑ −1 nt=2 (y t − y t−1 ) 2 <strong>for</strong> t > n. 7 The columns labeled delay reportthe mean number of observations necessary to detect explosiveness relative to the wholesample. Only those cases where the detection occurs after the true breakpo<strong>in</strong>t enter thecalculations. The same applies to the empirical standard deviation of the detection delayreported <strong>in</strong> the columns labeled σ(delay). Table 8 shows that the power of the CUSUMmonitor<strong>in</strong>g is comparable to that of the rDF procedure. The CUSUM monitor<strong>in</strong>g detectsbubbles slightly later. The fact that the mean and the standard deviation of the detectiondelay decrease as the regime switch occurs later is probably due to the decreas<strong>in</strong>g size ofthe <strong>in</strong>terval where explosiveness can be detected.7 Applications7.1 The Nasdaq Composite Index and the Dot.com BubbleA price movement <strong>for</strong> which the term bubble is widely used is that of the Nasdaq compositeprice <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong> the late 90s of the last century. A mere look at the plot of this time seriesappears to justify the name “dot.com bubble” (see figure 4). Phillips et al. (2009) foundempirical evidence that suggested that a rational bubble <strong>in</strong>deed was present. In thissection we reproduce their f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs and also apply the other test presented <strong>in</strong> section 2.The data we use is the same as that considered by Phillips et al. (2009). The times7 In pr<strong>in</strong>cipal one could update ˆσ 2 as new data arrive dur<strong>in</strong>g the monitor<strong>in</strong>g. This can lead to powerreduction and a higher detection delay s<strong>in</strong>ce ˆσ 2 would be deflated by <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g observations from theexplosive phase of the data generat<strong>in</strong>g process. However, <strong>in</strong> further simulations we found that thedeterioration <strong>in</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance is not substantial (not shown).17


series of the Nasdaq composite price <strong>in</strong>dex and the Nasdaq composite dividend yield aretaken from Datastream International. Phillips et al. (2009) considered monthly Nasdaqdata <strong>for</strong> an observation period from February 1973 to June 2005. However, if there wasbubble <strong>in</strong> the Nasdaq, figure 4 suggest that it has crashed <strong>in</strong> March 2000, when theNasdaq reached its peak. If the observations after the peak are <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the sample,the probability that the bubble tests will detect a bubble will be very low, even if it was<strong>in</strong>deed present, as was shown <strong>in</strong> section 5.3. There<strong>for</strong>e we apply the tests to the restrictedsample period from February 1973 to March 2000, which makes T = 326 observations.The Nasdaq composite price <strong>in</strong>dex is multiplied by the Nasdaq composite dividend yieldto compute the time series of the total Nasdaq dividends. By use of the Consumer PriceIndex from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, nom<strong>in</strong>al data are trans<strong>for</strong>med to realdata. Figure 4 shows a plot of the time series <strong>for</strong> the real Nasdaq price <strong>in</strong>dex and the realNasdaq dividends, where the time series have been normalized to 100 at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g ofthe observation period. While the price <strong>in</strong>dex shows a sharp <strong>in</strong>crease dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1990sfollowed by an at least equally sharp drop, real <strong>in</strong>dex dividends are more or less constant.For the logarithm of these two time series we conduct tests of the constant-I(1) hypothesisaga<strong>in</strong>st the alternative of a switch from I(1) to explosive. If the time series of theNasdaq composite price <strong>in</strong>dex turns out to have changed from I(1) to explosive, while the<strong>in</strong>dex dividend series rema<strong>in</strong>ed constant I(1), this would suggest the presence of bubbles.In the applications we follow Phillips, Wu, and Yu (2009) more closely and use anaugmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test that <strong>in</strong>cludes an <strong>in</strong>tercept term <strong>in</strong> the regression,i.e. the regression equation isy t = α + ρy t−1 +p∑φ j ∆y t−j + ɛ t , <strong>for</strong> t = 1, . . . , [τT ], (29)j=1where y t denotes the logarithm of either the Nasdaq price or dividends and ɛ t is whitenoise. The lag order p is determ<strong>in</strong>ed by a general-to-specific test sequence. (29) leads tothe augmented DF t-statistic ADF τ . The supremum of ADF τ over τ ∈ [0.2, 1] is referedto as supADF. The perta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g critical values are taken from Phillips et al. (2009).The results are shown <strong>in</strong> table 9. For the dividend series, none of the tests rejects theconstant I(1) hypothesis at the 5% significance level. Even at the 10% significance levelthe null hypothesis is not rejected. The application of the supADF test leads to resultsthat are very similar to those obta<strong>in</strong>ed by Phillips et al. (2009) 8 . The supDFC test andthe supBT test also detect explosivness <strong>in</strong> the Nasdaq <strong>in</strong>dex, while the supB test andthe supK test fail to reject the null hypothesis 9 . This reflects our f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> the MonteCarlo section. Those test which were found to be most powerful support the view that theNasdaq price <strong>in</strong>dex has changed from I(1) to explosive, while the dividend series rema<strong>in</strong>edI(1) throughout the whole sample. Under the assumption that the present value model<strong>in</strong> equations (2) and (3) is not misspecified, one may conclude that rational bubbles are8 They report a test value of 2.984 <strong>for</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dex price and a value of -1.018 <strong>for</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dex dividends9 We f<strong>in</strong>d similar results <strong>for</strong> the break test, when we apply them to the detrended series18


<strong>in</strong>deed present <strong>in</strong> the Nasdaq <strong>in</strong>dex.This leads to the question about when the bubble started. First consider the approachtaken by Phillips et al. (2009). Figure 5 conta<strong>in</strong>s the plots of the ADF τ statistic <strong>for</strong> thelog real Nasdaq price <strong>in</strong>dex (solid l<strong>in</strong>e). ADF τ is the augmented Dickey-Fuller t-statistic<strong>for</strong> the subsample {y 1 , . . . , y [τT ] }. Given on the x-axis is the period that corresponds tothe [τT ]-th observation. The estimated bubble start is June 1995, which is the first timethat the ADF τ statistic is greater than the 5% right-tail critical value of the asymptoticdistribution of the standard Dickey-Fuller t-statistic (−0.08). 10We also estimate the time of the bubble emergence us<strong>in</strong>g the estimator from theChow-style DF-statistic ˆτ DF C . The maximum of DF C τ is atta<strong>in</strong>ed at ˆτ DF C = 81, 3%.The correspond<strong>in</strong>g date is February 1995.From a different perspective, we can address the question about when the bubblewould have been detected, if the Nasdaq had been monitored. We assume that themonitor<strong>in</strong>g started <strong>in</strong> July 1979 with a tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g sample of 77 monthly observations (fromFebruary 1973 to June 1979) and apply the recursive (augmented) DF procedure. Thecorrespond<strong>in</strong>g critical value is 1.468 (see table 9). We f<strong>in</strong>d that the bubble would havebeen detected <strong>in</strong> July 1999 (see figure 5).7.2 The Hang Seng IndexThe Hang Seng Index is the ma<strong>in</strong> market <strong>in</strong>dicator at the Hong Kong stock exchange,which ranks among the largest stock exchanges <strong>in</strong> Asia. In the history of the Hang SengIndex traders have seen many phases of impressive growth followed by steep falls. For<strong>in</strong>stance, between October 1983 and October 1987 the <strong>in</strong>dex rose by more than 450% andthen lost half of its peak value until July 1989. Similarly, from May 2003 to November 2007the Hang Seng <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong>creased by almost 350%. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the subsequent global f<strong>in</strong>ancialcrisis it dropped by more than 60% with<strong>in</strong> 15 month. A graph is shown <strong>in</strong> figure 6 wherethe real Hang Seng <strong>in</strong>dex is plotted together with the correspond<strong>in</strong>g real dividends. Bothseries have been normalized to 100 at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the observation period.Data of the Hang Seng price <strong>in</strong>dex and dividend yield are taken from DatastreamInternational. These two series are used to calculate the Hang Seng dividends. In orderto trans<strong>for</strong>m nom<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>to real data we use the composite Consumer Price Index from theHong Kong Census and Statistics Department.We test wether the global f<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis has been preceded by a bubble <strong>in</strong> the HangSeng <strong>in</strong>dex. If there was a bubble, it has certa<strong>in</strong>ly burst <strong>in</strong> November 2007. There<strong>for</strong>e, wedo not <strong>in</strong>clude observations follow<strong>in</strong>g that date. Data on the composite Consumer PriceIndex <strong>for</strong> Honk Kong is only available from October 1980 on. Thus, <strong>for</strong> our <strong>in</strong>dex anddividend time series, we have 326 monthly observations from October 1980 to November2007 .10 Us<strong>in</strong>g log(log(τT ))/100 as critical value <strong>for</strong> ADF τ (cf. Phillips et al.(2009)) results <strong>in</strong> almost thesame estimate <strong>for</strong> the start of the bubble, namely July 1995.19


We apply our tests to the natural logarithm of the Hang Seng <strong>in</strong>dex and dividendseries. The results are reported <strong>in</strong> table 10. Regard<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>dex price, the only statisticthat is significant is that of the sequential Chow-type DF test, supDFC. This statistic isborderl<strong>in</strong>e significant at the 5% level. The other tests cannot reject the random walk nullhypothesis, even at the 10% level. Furthermore, the supDFC statistic <strong>for</strong> the dividendseries is not significant at the 10% level. Thus, given that the present value model <strong>in</strong>(2) and (3) is correctly specified, the supDFC test leads to the conclusion that, <strong>in</strong>deed,a bubble has preceded the outbreak of the global f<strong>in</strong>ancial crises. The other tests do notdetect an explosive movement <strong>in</strong> the Hang Seng <strong>in</strong>dex and hence do not corroborate theresult of the supDFC test. We ascribe this to the fact that most of those tests have lesspower than the supDFC test as our Monte Carlo analysis has shown.The detection of a bubble <strong>in</strong> the Hang Seng <strong>in</strong>dex by the supDFC test suggests theuse of the perta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g estimator ˆτ DF C to determ<strong>in</strong>e the date at which the bubble emerged.The result<strong>in</strong>g estimate is ˆτ DF C = 0.83 which corresponds to April 2003.8 ConclusionIn this paper the ability of several tests to detect rational bubbles has been <strong>in</strong>vestigated.The focus was on rational bubbles <strong>in</strong> stock markets. A basic standpo<strong>in</strong>t was that explosivestock prices together with nonexplosive dividends imply the presence of bubbles <strong>in</strong> theprice process. Hence, all tests aimed at detect<strong>in</strong>g a switch to explosiveness <strong>in</strong> a timeseries. The sequential Dickey-Fuller test, proposed by Phillips, Wu and Yu (2009) servedas a reference po<strong>in</strong>t. As opposed to Phillips et al.’s (2009) procedure the other tests wereconceived as tests <strong>for</strong> a structural break. In a simple simulation framework it was shownthat a Chow-type Dickey-Fuller test and a modified version of Busseti and Taylor’s (2004)test have higher f<strong>in</strong>ite sample power than the test of Phillips et al. (2009), especially whenthe change from I(1) to explosive occurs late <strong>in</strong> the sample. This result was confirmed <strong>in</strong>simulation experiments with randomly start<strong>in</strong>g bubbles.With regard to the estimation of the time of the bubble emergence, different proceduresto estimate the po<strong>in</strong>t of change from I(1) to explosive were considered. It turned outthat, <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ite samples, Phillips et al.’s (2009) estimator is downward biased. Moreover,this estimator has a very high standard deviation. It would be more reliable to use theestimator ˆτ DF C , which directly relates to the Chow-type Dickey-Fuller test.The consideration of Evans’ (1991) periodically collaps<strong>in</strong>g bubbles showed the weaknessof break tests <strong>in</strong> bubble detection. For these tests it is crucial that the bubble doesnot crash with<strong>in</strong> the last part of the sample.The sequential Dickey-Fuller test of Phillips et al. (2009) can also be conceived as amonitor<strong>in</strong>g procedure. We tabulated critical values <strong>for</strong> different sizes of the monitor<strong>in</strong>gsample. Moreover, we propose a simple CUSUM monitor<strong>in</strong>g scheme. The power and thedetection delay of the CUSUM monitor<strong>in</strong>g are comparable with those of the recursive DFprocedure.20


In the applications, Phillips et al.’s (2009) result that bubbles are present <strong>in</strong> theNasdaq <strong>in</strong>dex was confirmed by our sequential Chow-type Dickey-Fuller test as well asby the modified version of Busetti and Taylor’s (2004) test. The estimation of the dateof the bubble emergence <strong>in</strong>dicated that the explosive behavior <strong>in</strong> the Nasdaq started <strong>in</strong>the first half of the year 1995. The supDFC test also detected a bubble <strong>in</strong> the Hang Seng<strong>in</strong>dex. Our estimate <strong>for</strong> the start of this bubble is April 2003.21


ReferencesBai, J., and P. Perron (1998): “Estimat<strong>in</strong>g and test<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>in</strong>ear models with multiplestructural changes,” Econometrica, 66(1), 47–78.Bhargava, A. (1986): “On the theory of test<strong>in</strong>g <strong>for</strong> unit roots <strong>in</strong> observed time series,”Review of Economic Studies, 53, 369–384.Blanchard, O. J., and M. W. Watson (1982): “<strong>Bubbles</strong>, rational expectations, andf<strong>in</strong>ancial markets,” <strong>in</strong> Crisis <strong>in</strong> the economics f<strong>in</strong>ancial structure, ed. by P. Wachtel,pp. 295–315. Lex<strong>in</strong>gton Books, Lex<strong>in</strong>gton, Mass.Busetti, F., and A. M. R. Taylor (2004): “Tests of stationarity aga<strong>in</strong>st a change <strong>in</strong>persistence,” Journal of <strong>Econometrics</strong>, 123, 33–66.Campbell, J. Y., A. W. Lo, and A. C. MacK<strong>in</strong>lay (1997): The econometrics off<strong>in</strong>ancial markets. Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton Univ. Press, Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton, NJ.Campbell, J. Y., and R. J. Shiller (1987): “Co<strong>in</strong>tegration and tests of present valuemodels,” Journal of Political Economy, 95, 1062–1088.Campbell, J. Y., and R. J. Shiller (1988): “The dividend-price ratio and expectationsof future dividends and discount factors,” Review of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Studies, 1(3), 195–228.Chong, T. T.-L. (2001): “Structural change <strong>in</strong> AR(1) models,” Econometric Theory, 17,87–155.Chu, C.-S. J., M. St<strong>in</strong>chombe, and H. White (1996): “Monitor<strong>in</strong>g structural change,”Econometrica, 64, 1045–1065.Cuñado, J., L. A. Gil-Alana, and F. P. de Gracia (2005): “A test <strong>for</strong> rationalbubbles <strong>in</strong> the NASDAQ stock <strong>in</strong>dex: a fractionally <strong>in</strong>tegrated approach,” Journal ofBank<strong>in</strong>g and F<strong>in</strong>ance, 29, 2633–2654.Diba, B. T., and H. I. Grossman (1988): “Explosive rational bubbles <strong>in</strong> stock prices?,”American Economic Review, 78(3), 520–530.Evans, G. W. (1991): “Pitfalls <strong>in</strong> test<strong>in</strong>g <strong>for</strong> explosive bubbles <strong>in</strong> asset prices,” AmericanEconomic Review, 81(4), 922–930.Froot, K., and M. Obstfeld (1991): “Intr<strong>in</strong>sic bubbles: the case of stock prices,”American Economic Review, 81, 1189–1214.Fuller, W. A. (1996): Introduction to statistical time series. Wiley, New York, 2 edn.Galbraith, J. K. (1993): A short history of f<strong>in</strong>ancial euphoria. Vik<strong>in</strong>g, New York.22


Gürkaynak, R. S. (2008): “Econometric tests of asset price bubbles: tak<strong>in</strong>g stock,”Journal of Economic Surveys, 22(1), 166–186.Hall, S. G., Z. Psaradakis, and M. Sola (1999): “Detect<strong>in</strong>g periodically collaps<strong>in</strong>gbubbles: a Markow-switch<strong>in</strong>g unit root test,” Journal of Applied <strong>Econometrics</strong>, 14,143–154.Hamilton, J. D. (1994): Time series analysis. Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton Univ. Press, Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton, NJ.Kim, J.-Y. (2000): “Detection of change <strong>in</strong> persistence of a l<strong>in</strong>ear time series,” Journalof <strong>Econometrics</strong>, 95, 97–116.Kim, J.-Y., J. Belaire-Franch, and R. B. Amador (2002): “Corrigendum to ‘Detectionof change <strong>in</strong> pers<strong>in</strong>stence of a l<strong>in</strong>ear time series’,” Journal of <strong>Econometrics</strong>, 109,389–392.Kruse, R. (2008): “Rational bubbles and chang<strong>in</strong>g degree of fractional <strong>in</strong>tegration,”Diskussionspapiere der Wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen Fakultät der Universität Hannover,number dp-394.LeRoy, S. F., and R. D. Porter (1981): “The present-value relation: Tests based onimplied variance bounds,” Econometrica, 49, 555–574.Leybourne, S., T.-H. Kim, V. Smith, and P. Newbold (2003): “Tests <strong>for</strong> a change<strong>in</strong> persistence aga<strong>in</strong>st the null off difference-stationarity,” The <strong>Econometrics</strong> Journal,6(2), 291–311.Phillips, P. C. B., Y. Wu, and J. Yu (2009): “Explosive behavior <strong>in</strong> the 1990s Nasdaq:When did exuberance escalate asset values?,” Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No.1699.Shiller, R. J. (2001): Irrational exuberance. Broadway Books, New York.Van Norden, S., and R. Vigfusson (1998): “Avoid<strong>in</strong>g the pitfalls: can regimeswitch<strong>in</strong>gtests reliably detect bubbles?,” Studies <strong>in</strong> Nonl<strong>in</strong>ear Dynamics andEconomectrics, 3, 1–22.West, K. (1987): “A specification test <strong>for</strong> speculative bubbles,” Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, 102, 553–580.(1988): “<strong>Bubbles</strong>, fads, and stock price volatility tests: a partial evaluation,”Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance, 43, 639–655.Zeileis, A., F. Leisch, C. Kleiber, and K. Hornik (2005): “Monitor<strong>in</strong>g structuralchange <strong>in</strong> dynamic econometric models,” Journal of Applied <strong>Econometrics</strong>, 20, 99–121.23


Table 1: Upper Tail Critical ValuesSample size Quantiles Test statisticssupDF supDFC supK supBT supB(a) Critical values without detrend<strong>in</strong>gT=100 0.90 2.1944 1.5422 28.4766 2.0004 2.84980.95 2.5671 1.9290 40.0557 2.5396 3.32130.99 3.2778 2.5950 74.8903 3.8404 4.3459T=200 0.90 2.2145 1.5709 29.1150 1.9459 3.03530.95 2.5841 1.9206 39.6741 2.4691 3.54630.99 3.2055 2.6022 72.9779 3.7759 4.8781T=400 0.90 2.2374 1.5527 29.4079 1.9496 3.05200.95 2.5980 1.9155 40.7870 2.4397 3.59350.99 3.2227 2.5882 75.7367 3.7150 4.9529(b) Critical values with detrend<strong>in</strong>gT=100 0.90 0.0599 0.9071 24.294 1.8448 2.35140.95 0.3206 1.2864 33.729 2.3928 2.77200.99 0.7871 2.0408 55.935 3.7456 3.6201T=200 0.90 0.1006 0.9108 24.948 1.7766 2.48050.95 0.3402 1.2709 34.067 2.2800 2.96360.99 0.7753 2.0436 59.077 3.6151 3.9984T=400 0.90 0.1192 0.9542 26.692 1.7661 2.62400.95 0.3562 1.3451 36.402 2.3116 3.16170.99 0.8264 2.0168 62.729 3.5697 4.3906Notes: The critical values are estimated by simulation of (9) - (10) with 10.000 replications.24


Table 2: Empirical powerBreak po<strong>in</strong>tTest statistics(a) Power <strong>for</strong> T = 100supDF supDFC supK supBT supBτ ∗ = 0.7 ρ = 1.02 0.171 0.311 0.094 0.267 0.180ρ = 1.03 0.293 0.479 0.144 0.441 0.298ρ = 1.04 0.431 0.632 0.221 0.593 0.433ρ = 1.05 0.562 0.741 0.328 0.721 0.541τ ∗ = 0.8 ρ = 1.02 0.108 0.240 0.079 0.195 0.125ρ = 1.03 0.174 0.366 0.099 0.324 0.176ρ = 1.04 0.260 0.485 0.129 0.444 0.251ρ = 1.05 0.353 0.584 0.173 0.558 0.326τ ∗ = 0.9 ρ = 1.02 0.069 0.147 0.062 0.115 0.068(b) Power <strong>for</strong> T = 200ρ = 1.03 0.086 0.215 0.066 0.173 0.073ρ = 1.04 0.109 0.291 0.073 0.245 0.076ρ = 1.05 0.140 0.367 0.079 0.324 0.071τ ∗ 0.7 1.02 0.441 0.630 0.234 0.608 0.4851.03 0.669 0.811 0.477 0.801 0.7011.04 0.820 0.899 0.770 0.897 0.8311.05 0.894 0.945 0.896 0.945 0.892τ ∗ 0.8 1.02 0.269 0.496 0.156 0.460 0.3161.03 0.467 0.688 0.249 0.673 0.5161.04 0.636 0.799 0.445 0.792 0.6661.05 0.748 0.869 0.692 0.869 0.758τ ∗ 0.9 1.02 0.108 0.313 0.080 0.268 0.1141.03 0.178 0.465 0.102 0.430 0.1831.04 0.284 0.590 0.134 0.562 0.2501.05 0.385 0.686 0.183 0.676 0.325Notes: The empirical power is computed at a nom<strong>in</strong>al size of 5%. The simulations are conducted with2, 000 replications of (9) and (11). The true (simulated) breakpo<strong>in</strong>t τ ∗ is measured relative to the samplesize. ρ is the autoregressive slope parameter under the explosive regime.25


Table 3: Empirical power cont.Break po<strong>in</strong>tTest statistics(c) Power <strong>for</strong> T = 400supDF supDFC supK supBT supBτ ∗ = 0.7 ρ = 1.02 0.825 0.901 0.766 0.901 0.864ρ = 1.03 0.939 0.970 0.945 0.970 0.951ρ = 1.04 0.978 0.989 0.979 0.989 0.980ρ = 1.05 0.994 0.998 0.995 0.998 0.994τ ∗ = 0.8 ρ = 1.02 0.644 0.815 0.471 0.809 0.707ρ = 1.03 0.848 0.927 0.822 0.931 0.871ρ = 1.04 0.938 0.972 0.933 0.972 0.941ρ = 1.05 0.971 0.986 0.977 0.987 0.973τ ∗ = 0.9 ρ = 1.02 0.299 0.582 0.116 0.565 0.361ρ = 1.03 0.498 0.762 0.273 0.763 0.548ρ = 1.04 0.660 0.860 0.540 0.863 0.681ρ = 1.05 0.771 0.910 0.720 0.915 0.753Notes: The empirical power is computed at a nom<strong>in</strong>al size of 5%. The simulations are conducted with2, 000 replications of (9) and (11). The true (simulated) breakpo<strong>in</strong>t τ ∗ is measured relative to the samplesize. ρ is the autoregressive slope parameter under the explosive regime.26


Table 4: Rejection frequencies <strong>in</strong> the case of randomly start<strong>in</strong>g bubblesInitial value π Test statisticssupDF supDFC supK supBT supBRejection frequencies when the sample size is T = 100B 0 = 2 no bubble 0.053 0.046 0.050 0.049 0.0410.02 0.481 0.654 0.073 0.636 0.5140.05 0.522 0.737 0.078 0.730 0.5560.10 0.515 0.851 0.081 0.837 0.5890.25 0.493 0.919 0.093 0.902 0.5870.50 0.503 0.943 0.097 0.924 0.5901.00 0.502 0.946 0.097 0.930 0.587Rejection frequencies when the sample size is T = 200B 0 = 0.05 0.01 0.580 0.656 0.112 0.651 0.5870.02 0.695 0.767 0.151 0.768 0.6990.05 0.893 0.945 0.211 0.948 0.8910.10 0.980 0.993 0.221 0.995 0.976Notes: The tests are applied to series generated as P t = P f t + B t , with P f t as <strong>in</strong> (8) and B t as <strong>in</strong> (22).2000 replications are per<strong>for</strong>med. The “no-bubble” hypothesis is rejected when the test statistic exceedsthe 95% quantile from table 1. B 0 is the <strong>in</strong>itial value of the bubble. π is the probability that the bubbleenters the phase of explosive growth.27


Table 5: Rejection frequencies <strong>in</strong> the case of periodically collaps<strong>in</strong>g bubblesSample size π Test statisticssupDF supDFC supK supBT supBT=100 no bubble 0.053 0.046 0.050 0.049 0.0410.999 0.902 0.899 0.043 0.931 0.2900.990 0.887 0.593 0.220 0.646 0.2900.950 0.764 0.179 0.390 0.213 0.1460.850 0.624 0.072 0.330 0.073 0.0420.750 0.531 0.053 0.303 0.044 0.0320.500 0.365 0.025 0.233 0.028 0.0270.250 0.253 0.023 0.210 0.021 0.033Notes: The tests are applied to series generated as P t = P f t + 20B t , with P f t as <strong>in</strong> (8) and B t as <strong>in</strong> (23).2000 replications are per<strong>for</strong>med. The “no-bubble” hypothesis is rejected when the test statistic exceedsits 95% quantile from table 1. π is the probability that the bubble does not collapse <strong>in</strong> the next period.28


Table 6: Estimated break dates when ρ = 1.05Break po<strong>in</strong>t Sample Size T=200 Sample Size T=400ˆτ P ˆτ DF C ˆτ BT ˆτ P ˆτ DF C ˆτ BTτ ∗ = 0.4 0.4840 0.4616 0.6564 0.4258 0.4232 0.4901(0.1558) (0.1037) (0.1334) (0.1049) (0.0456) (0.0601)τ ∗ = 0.5 0.5498 0.5582 0.7636 0.4987 0.5207 0.5933(0.1873) (0.0980) (0.1137) (0.1410) (0.0436) (0.0616)τ ∗ = 0.6 0.6089 0.6493 0.8577 0.5688 0.6208 0.6991(0.2185) (0.0862) (0.0692) (0.1803) (0.0441) (0.0621)τ ∗ = 0.7 0.6554 0.7388 0.8967 0.6355 0.7207 0.8080(0.2523) (0.0747) (0.0149) (0.2216) (0.0427) (0.0548)τ ∗ = 0.8 0.6800 0.8186 0.8990 0.6937 0.8143 0.8903(0.2875) (0.0594) (0.0036) (0.2603) (0.0329) (0.0185)τ ∗ = 0.9 0.6299 0.8701 0.8978 0.7145 0.8890 0.8996(0.3208) (0.0775) (0.0071) (0.3032) (0.0512) (0.0023)Notes: The table reports mean values and standard deviations (<strong>in</strong> parentheses) of the break po<strong>in</strong>t estimatorsˆτ P , ˆτ DF C and ˆτ K . These values as well as the true breakpo<strong>in</strong>t τ ∗ are expressed as fraction of thesample size T . Data is generated accord<strong>in</strong>g to equation (9) and (11) <strong>for</strong> the sample size T = 200 andT = 400. The autoregressive slope parameter under the explosive regime is ρ = 1.05. In each case 1000replications are per<strong>for</strong>med.29


Table 7: Critical Values <strong>for</strong> Fluctuation Monitor<strong>in</strong>g (rDF)N 50 75 100 120 150 200 250 300α0.10 2.2877 2.3529 2.4073 2.4267 2.4520 2.4853 2.5163 2.53020.05 2.5987 2.6679 2.7242 2.7331 2.7633 2.7934 2.8181 2.83250.01 3.1577 3.2286 3.2835 3.2971 3.3229 3.3316 3.3485 3.3596N 400 500 600 750 1000 1500 2000 2500α0.10 2.5753 2.5979 2.6164 2.6345 2.6657 2.7017 2.7186 2.73350.05 2.8636 2.8809 2.9006 2.9123 2.9353 2.9691 2.9931 3.00950.01 3.3904 3.4108 3.4335 3.4579 3.5006 3.5152 3.5329 3.5470Notes: The table shows critical values <strong>for</strong> different sample sizes N and significance levels α. For thesimulation of the critical values 10, 000 replications of the DGP <strong>in</strong> (9) and (10) were carried out.30


Table 8: Per<strong>for</strong>mance of Monitor<strong>in</strong>g ProceduresrDFCUSUMBreakpo<strong>in</strong>t size/ power delay σ(delay) size/ power delay σ(delay)a) size of tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g sample n = 40, size of total sample kn = 200no break 0.0412 — — 0.0358 — —τ ∗ = 0.2 0.9756 0.2886 0.1748 0.9712 0.3081 0.1626τ ∗ = 0.4 0.9314 0.2503 0.1371 0.9198 0.2601 0.1354τ ∗ = 0.6 0.8086 0.2040 0.0969 0.7758 0.2139 0.0961τ ∗ = 0.8 0.4560 0.1256 0.0464 0.3900 0.1288 0.0473b) size of tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g sample n = 80, size of total sample kn = 400no break 0.0332 — — 0.0286 — —τ ∗ = 0.2 0.9996 0.1420 0.0970 0.9996 0.1572 0.0928τ ∗ = 0.4 0.9972 0.1339 0.0896 0.9966 0.1454 0.0912τ ∗ = 0.6 0.9850 0.1263 0.0781 0.9816 0.1381 0.0805τ ∗ = 0.8 0.8300 0.0978 0.0469 0.7870 0.1058 0.0480Notes: The data is generated as a random walk switch<strong>in</strong>g to explosive at the relative break po<strong>in</strong>t τ ∗ (cf.(9) and (11)). The number of replications is 5, 000. The size/ power is computed at the 5% significancelevel. In the column delay we report the average time needed to detect the regime switch relative tothe sample size kn. Detections that occur prior to the true break (type I error) are removed from thecalculation. The column σ(delay) conta<strong>in</strong>s standard deviations of the detection delay relative to thesample size.31


Table 9: <strong>Test<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>for</strong> an explosive root <strong>in</strong> the Nasdaq <strong>in</strong>dexTest StatisticssupADF supDFC supK supBT supBlog price <strong>in</strong>dex 3.0467 4.5874 12.5203 7.8722 3.0242log dividends -0.9974 -0.2086 5.0756 0.1438 2.0057Upper tail critical values1% 2.094 2.5882 75.7367 3.715 4.95925% 1.468 1.9155 40.787 2.4397 3.593510% 1.184 1.5527 29.4079 1.9496 3.0520Notes: Table 9 reports the values of the test statistics applied to the log real Nasdaq price <strong>in</strong>dex anddividends. The table also shows the correspond<strong>in</strong>g critical values. Those <strong>for</strong> the supADF statistic aretaken from Phillips et al. (2009). The others correspond to our simulation results.32


Table 10: <strong>Test<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>for</strong> an explosive root <strong>in</strong> the Hang Seng <strong>in</strong>dexTest StatisticssupADF supDFC supK supBT supBlog price <strong>in</strong>dex -0.1538 1.933 4.6439 1.3842 2.6096log dividends 0.2644 1.1578 40.6668 0.7147 2.4152Upper tail critical values1% 2.094 2.5882 75.7367 3.715 4.95925% 1.468 1.9155 40.787 2.4397 3.593510% 1.184 1.5527 29.4079 1.9496 3.0520Notes: Table 10 reports the values of the test statistics applied to the log real Hang Seng price <strong>in</strong>dex anddividends. The table also shows the correspond<strong>in</strong>g critical values. Those <strong>for</strong> the supADF statistic aretaken from Phillips et al. (2009). The others correspond to our simulation results.33


Price and Fundamental component25020015010050pricefundamental component00 20 40 60 80 100PeriodFigure 1: Simulated price series with randomly start<strong>in</strong>g bubble component34


Price and Fundamental component35030025020015010050pricefundamental componentBubble component3002502001501005000 20 40 60 80 100Period00 20 40 60 80 100PeriodFigure 2: Simulated price with fundamental component (left) and bubble component(right)35


Price3503002502001501005000 20 40 60 80 100PeriodDF τ−Statistic210−1−2−3−40 20 40 60 80 100Size of Sample PeriodFigure 3: Price Conta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Periodically Collaps<strong>in</strong>g Bubble (left) and DF τ -Statistic (right)36


12001000Real Nasdaq PriceReal Nasdaq Dividends8006004002000Jan70 Jan80 Jan90 Jan00 Jan10PeriodFigure 4: Real Nasdaq Price and Dividends (normalized)37


432July 199910−1−2June 1995−3−4Jan75 Jan80 Jan85 Jan90 Jan95 Jan00 Jan05 Jan10Figure 5: ADF τ Statistics <strong>for</strong> (log) real Nasdaq prices (solid l<strong>in</strong>e), with 5% right tailcritical value from asymptotic distribution of the standard Dickey-Fuller t-statistic (dottedl<strong>in</strong>e) and the f<strong>in</strong>ite sample 5% right tail critical value <strong>for</strong> the supADF statistic with T=400observations (dash-dotted l<strong>in</strong>e)38


700600500Real Hang Seng Price IndexReal Hang Seng Dividends4003002001000Jan80 Jan85 Jan90 Jan95 Jan00 Jan05 Jan10PeriodFigure 6: Real Hang Seng Index and Dividends (normalized)39

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!