11.07.2015 Views

What does it mean and how do savings banks foster access - Wsbi

What does it mean and how do savings banks foster access - Wsbi

What does it mean and how do savings banks foster access - Wsbi

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

ACCESS TO FINANCE –WHAT DOES IT MEAN ANDHOW DO SAVINGS BANKSFOSTER ACCESSA study for the World Savings Banks Inst<strong>it</strong>ute (WSBI)By Stephen Peachey <strong>and</strong> Alan Roe,Oxford Policy Management


AcknowledgementsThe authors would like to express their profound thanks for the supportprovided by the WSBI <strong>and</strong> the staff of <strong>it</strong>s Joint Office w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>it</strong>s sister inst<strong>it</strong>ution,the European Savings Banks Group (ESBG). We would also like to thankmember inst<strong>it</strong>utions of the WSBI/ESBG that provided inputs on <strong>savings</strong> bankin<strong>it</strong>iatives to improve <strong>access</strong> to finance. Four individuals – Angela Arevalo,Julie Ansidei, Mark Bienstman <strong>and</strong> Antonique Koning – from the JointOffice deserve our particular thanks for organising the work <strong>and</strong> memberinputs.None of the analysis would have been possible w<strong>it</strong>hout the placing ofresearch papers on the internet <strong>and</strong> particularly heavy use was made ofCGAP, World Bank <strong>and</strong> European Commission web-s<strong>it</strong>es. The authorswould particularly like to thank Thorsten Beck, Asli Demirguc-Kunt <strong>and</strong>Stijn Claessens of World Bank for comments on the paper <strong>and</strong> for allowingus to quote from forthcoming papers. The analysis on the role of <strong>savings</strong><strong>banks</strong> in providing <strong>access</strong>ible accounts would not have been possiblew<strong>it</strong>hout the groundbreaking study by Rich Rosenberg <strong>and</strong> his team atCGAP on <strong>do</strong>uble bottom-line inst<strong>it</strong>utions quoted extensively in the study.Finally, we would like to thank Tini Chatterjee <strong>and</strong> Clare O’Brien ofOxford Policy Management for all their hard work in pulling togetherresearch material that underpins much of this study.ACCESS TO FINANCE –WHAT DOES IT MEAN ANDHOW DO SAVINGS BANKSFOSTER ACCESSTable of ContentsPreface 5List of Tables, Figures <strong>and</strong> Boxes 9Foreword 111. Executive Summary 13A. Purpose of the study <strong>and</strong> objectives 13B. Conceptual framework – Access versus Exclusion 13C. Access as an element in successful economic development 14D. Ways of measuring <strong>access</strong> 15E. Differences in <strong>access</strong> across countries <strong>and</strong> regions 16F. The main constraints in different countries <strong>and</strong> regions 17G. Public mechanisms for stimulating <strong>access</strong> to finance 18H. Banking in<strong>it</strong>iatives to maintain <strong>and</strong> improve <strong>access</strong>to finance 19I. <strong>What</strong> more needs to be <strong>do</strong>ne by the private<strong>and</strong> public sector 20J. The role of the <strong>savings</strong> bank movement in developing <strong>access</strong> 21K. Conclusions 222. The Nature of Access: An Overview of the L<strong>it</strong>erature 23Part One: Introduction <strong>and</strong> the Role of Finance 23A. Introduction 23B. Does finance matter <strong>and</strong> if so why? 24Part Two: Exclusion in Richer Countries 30C. The scale of individual financial exclusion in richer countries 30D. Causes of improving <strong>access</strong> 34E. Characteristics of excluded individuals 37F. Access for enterprises – microcred<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong>small business lending 4267


Part Three: Issues in the Developing Countries 46G. The overall scale of financial systems in developing countries 46H. The value of improved individual <strong>access</strong>in developing countries 47I. Problems w<strong>it</strong>h enterprise <strong>access</strong> in developing countries 48J. Supply constraints on <strong>access</strong> to banking <strong>and</strong> microfinance 53K. Other issues affecting <strong>access</strong> in developing countries 603. Dimensions of Access in Different Regions 65A. Overview 65B. Metho<strong>do</strong>logy for overcoming the lack of solid dataon <strong>access</strong> 684. Public Policy <strong>and</strong> Bank Responses to Issues of Access 83A. Overview 83B. Public policy measures to enhance individual <strong>access</strong> 83C. Public policy measures to enhance enterprise <strong>access</strong> 92D. Banking sector responses to financial exclusionin advanced economies 93E. Banking sector responses to issues of <strong>access</strong>in developing economies 95F. Implications for future policy 975. The Role of Savings Banks 99A. Overview 99B. The importance of proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> to levels of <strong>access</strong> 99C. <strong>What</strong> proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> <strong>do</strong> to improve individual <strong>access</strong> 104D. <strong>What</strong> proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> <strong>do</strong> specifically to improveenterprise <strong>access</strong> 115E. Policy as <strong>it</strong> affects proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> effortsto improve <strong>access</strong> 1166. A Brief Policy Agenda Emerging from the Analysis 1207. References / Bibliography 125List of Tables, Figures <strong>and</strong> BoxesTable 1: Availabil<strong>it</strong>y of a personal current account,giro account or similar 31Table 2: Loan processing costs for microcred<strong>it</strong>sin eight European economies 44Table 3: Enterprise financing patterns by size of firm<strong>and</strong> region 51Table 4: E-Finance penetration; projected through 2010 (percent) 62Table 5: Proportion of surveyed (adult) populationw<strong>it</strong>h bank/<strong>savings</strong> accounts 67Table 6: Commercial <strong>and</strong> <strong>savings</strong> bank accounts per hea<strong>do</strong>f adult population 67Table 7: Summary grading of countries by merged metho<strong>do</strong>f assessing <strong>access</strong> 78Table 8: Summary indicators of <strong>access</strong> across different regions 79Table 9: Development indicators for countries groupedby region <strong>and</strong> <strong>access</strong> 80Table 10: MAP summary of financial instruments for supportingEuropean SMEs 92Table 11: BRI-UD bank – a ten-year progression 96Table 12: Average depos<strong>it</strong> balances by country income group 108Table 13: Accounts h<strong>and</strong>led per <strong>savings</strong> bank employee,by location of outlet 111Table 14: Sample calculations of cost of use for a passbook 112Table 15: Outline Policy Matrix: responsibil<strong>it</strong>ies <strong>and</strong> timescales 124FiguresFigure 1: Financial system development across countryincome groups 46Figure 2: Operating costs as % earning assets 54Figure 3: Operating income as % earning assets 55Figure 4: MFI penetration (% of population) 56Figure 5: CGAP Matrix for addressing regions affectedby HIV/AIDS 63Figure 6: Proportion of South african population usingkey banking services 66Figure 7: Use of cash versus depos<strong>it</strong>s – link to the role ofthe banking system 70Figure 8: Use of cash versus depos<strong>it</strong>s – link to customer type 7089


Figure 9: Use of cash versus depos<strong>it</strong>s – implied level of <strong>access</strong> 72Figure 10: Suppliers of <strong>access</strong>ible accounts in developing/trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies 74Figure 11: Spectrum of <strong>access</strong> as s<strong>how</strong>n by <strong>access</strong>ible accountsper adult 75Figure 12: Ownership, prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> degree of <strong>access</strong> compared 101Figure 13: Ownership, prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> SME dissatisfactionw<strong>it</strong>h <strong>access</strong> 102Figure 14: Savings bank cost to asset ratios by region 109Figure 15: Savings bank staff productiv<strong>it</strong>y 110BoxesBox 1: Financial l<strong>it</strong>eracy <strong>and</strong> the impact on <strong>access</strong> 32Box 2: How the vulnerable acquire cred<strong>it</strong> in the UK 39Box 3: Banking costs <strong>and</strong> the scale of banking activ<strong>it</strong>y 54Box 4: Mobile phones in the developing world 61Box 5: The commun<strong>it</strong>y reinvestment act: objectives,methods <strong>and</strong> evaluation 85Box 6: Turning income into <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> cred<strong>it</strong> opportun<strong>it</strong>ies –Brazil, Mexico & Spain 106Box 7: Selected member in<strong>it</strong>iatives to <strong>foster</strong> microenterprisein advanced economies 117FOREWORDACCESS TO FINANCE IS AN ESSENTIAL driver for economic growth indeveloping <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies. It is also important in developedeconomies, where <strong>it</strong> stimulates markedly the social inclusion of certaingroups of the population. Access to finance empowers people, givesthem the opportun<strong>it</strong>y to have an account, to save <strong>and</strong> invest, to insuretheir homes or to take a loan <strong>and</strong> – in many cases – to break the chainsof poverty.That is why <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> socially comm<strong>it</strong>ted retail <strong>banks</strong> have made<strong>access</strong> to finance one of the underlying principles of their businessactiv<strong>it</strong>ies. Savings <strong>and</strong> socially comm<strong>it</strong>ted retail <strong>banks</strong> are well pos<strong>it</strong>ioned tosucceed in enhancing this <strong>access</strong> on a global level; they are trad<strong>it</strong>ionallyvery close to their customers, thanks to their extensive regional branchnetworks <strong>and</strong> the provision of low threshold products <strong>and</strong> services.The key role that <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> play in providing <strong>access</strong> to finance isillustrated in a most striking way by one of the conclusions of this study:three quarters of an estimated 1.4 billion <strong>access</strong>ible (low average balance,low-cost) accounts across the developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies aremanaged by <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong>!Thanks to their country-wide network <strong>and</strong> easy to <strong>access</strong> products <strong>and</strong>services, <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> are able to capture an important part of the<strong>savings</strong>, bringing in this way considerable parts of the world populationin the formal financial sector. Furthermore, <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> recycle morethan half of their depos<strong>it</strong>s as cred<strong>it</strong>s, which <strong>mean</strong>s that they play anessential role in the field of consumer banking, micro financing <strong>and</strong>financial services to small <strong>and</strong> medium enterprises.1011


This study proves clearly that an economy increases <strong>it</strong>s chances to achievefull <strong>access</strong> when a strong <strong>savings</strong> bank sector or another form of proxim<strong>it</strong>ybanking is present. Regulators should take this into account <strong>and</strong> provide alevel playing field for all financial players. Rules <strong>and</strong> regulations should befine-tuned to serve not only the interests of global players but also thoseof regional players. Only a pluralistic retail banking market can serve allthe interests of all the private customers <strong>and</strong> SMEs, including those ofcustomers in remote areas <strong>and</strong> those of less sophisticated clients.The World Savings Banks Inst<strong>it</strong>ute (WSBI) who has commissioned thisstudy is proud to present this thought-provoking <strong>and</strong> in many waysground-breaking <strong>do</strong>cument. We hope the interested reader will gain arefreshing insight to the Access to Finance debate.Chris De NooseChairman of the Management Comm<strong>it</strong>tee, WSBI1. EXECUTIVE SUMMARYA. Purpose of the study <strong>and</strong> objectivesThe purpose of this study is to give an overview of the importance of<strong>access</strong> to finance for all <strong>and</strong> to record the main obstacles to <strong>access</strong> indifferent parts of the world. It also attempts to create a coherent frameworkfor analysing the available data on <strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> to link this through toindicators of wider economic development. Having surveyed the nature<strong>and</strong> dimensions of <strong>access</strong> (or lack of <strong>it</strong>), the study goes on to review public<strong>and</strong> banking sector in<strong>it</strong>iatives to improve <strong>access</strong> to finance <strong>and</strong> then looksat the cr<strong>it</strong>ical role of the <strong>savings</strong> bank movement – socially comm<strong>it</strong>tedretail <strong>banks</strong>, like <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong>, postal <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> commun<strong>it</strong>y<strong>banks</strong> – in the provision of financial services to all strata of the populationin urban <strong>and</strong> more remote areas. Finally, a policy agenda is developed forboth the financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions that must deliver <strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> the publicsector that must create the right environment for <strong>do</strong>ing so.B. Conceptual framework – Access versus ExclusionIn assembling the study <strong>it</strong> proved useful to distinguish the l<strong>it</strong>erature, <strong>and</strong>even the language, that relates to low-income developing countries fromthat relating to advanced industrial economies such as those in theEuropean Union, North America <strong>and</strong> on the Pacific Rim. This is because<strong>access</strong> to formal financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions is frequently the preserve of qu<strong>it</strong>e asmall minor<strong>it</strong>y in low-income countries (<strong>and</strong> in the most repressed cases<strong>access</strong> will be measured in single percentage points of the widerpopulation). By contrast <strong>it</strong> is rare not to have at least some <strong>access</strong> to basicfinancial services in major industrial societies. This has <strong>mean</strong>t that thedebate in the developed world has focused on <strong>how</strong> people can come tobe excluded from <strong>access</strong> whether by active design or accident. Again, inmost cases in advanced industrial economies exclusion will be measuredin single percentage points of the population.1213


If readers want a simple propos<strong>it</strong>ion to fix the contrasts, theycan note that the percentage rate of <strong>access</strong> in poorer developingeconomies is about equal to the percentage rate of exclusion inricher advanced industrial economies. For this reason the debate about<strong>access</strong> to finance in developing economies is just part of the much widerdebate about <strong>access</strong> to basic needs from water, health, <strong>and</strong> education<strong>and</strong> through to roads, employment <strong>and</strong> communications. By contrast thedebate about financial exclusion in advanced industrial economies isfirmly lodged in wider debates about social exclusion <strong>and</strong> the welfare <strong>and</strong>criminal costs of people falling through the social fabric that sustains veryhigh levels of economic development.C. Access as an element in successful economicdevelopmentThere is clear <strong>and</strong> well established evidence that bigger <strong>and</strong> deeper bankingsystems go h<strong>and</strong> in h<strong>and</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h more advanced economic development<strong>and</strong> that a vibrant microfinance sector can augment this but not subst<strong>it</strong>utefor <strong>it</strong>. This is hardly surprising. Economic theory highlights the importanceof cap<strong>it</strong>al <strong>and</strong> trade to growth but also s<strong>how</strong>s that the creation of productivecap<strong>it</strong>al is as much about <strong>it</strong>s financing as <strong>it</strong>s existence. This is borne outby the data analysis in Chapter 3, which indicates a strong correlationbetween <strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> per-cap<strong>it</strong>a GDP w<strong>it</strong>hin regions <strong>and</strong> also acrossregions. Active trading is v<strong>it</strong>al to productiv<strong>it</strong>y gains but trade cannot takeplace w<strong>it</strong>hout a <strong>mean</strong>s of exchange. The purest purpose of money – inparticular in a dematerialised form – is to serve as a more efficient <strong>mean</strong>sof exchange than <strong>do</strong> barter <strong>and</strong> counter-trade. The purpose of bankbasedmoney as opposed to pure cash is two-fold. First, <strong>it</strong> is a better storeof value. Second, <strong>it</strong> allows economies to gear up their working cap<strong>it</strong>al(<strong>savings</strong>) to form also a platform for long-term cap<strong>it</strong>al (investment) throughthe matur<strong>it</strong>y transformation process that only <strong>banks</strong> can effectively make.Again, the data analysis bears this out, w<strong>it</strong>h lower cash-to-depos<strong>it</strong> ratios<strong>and</strong> higher depos<strong>it</strong>-to-GDP ratios associated w<strong>it</strong>h higher levels of per-cap<strong>it</strong>aGDP. Obviously money, <strong>and</strong> more particularly bank-based money, canonly provide these advantages when the transaction costs of operating abank account are below the inefficiency costs (<strong>and</strong> middle-man’s margin)of managing barter <strong>and</strong> counter-trade. All this is particularly crucial inpoorer developing countries, where evidence from the microfinancearena s<strong>how</strong>s that availabil<strong>it</strong>y of cred<strong>it</strong> <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> increase economic activ<strong>it</strong>y butto become financially self-sustaining, this has to be augmented by smallscale<strong>savings</strong> mobilisation.D. Ways of measuring <strong>access</strong>Access, <strong>and</strong> <strong>it</strong>s counterpart exclusion, are both surprisingly hard to measure.At the heart of this problem are three weaknesses in the way bankingdata are prepared: (a) data on numbers of people <strong>access</strong>ing personalfinancial services may often not even be known w<strong>it</strong>hin <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> otherinst<strong>it</strong>utions supplying the services, (b) regulators (until very recently) havenot been interested in retail transaction volumes, concentrating instea<strong>do</strong>n data relating to balance sheet stabil<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> (c) identification of SMEactiv<strong>it</strong>y is very poor <strong>and</strong> even worse for micro-enterprises. A few surveysdirectly address the issue in advanced industrial economies <strong>and</strong> theses<strong>how</strong> that on average nine out of ten surveyed adults in advancedindustrial economies have at least some sort of bank depos<strong>it</strong> or giropayments account. Unfortunately there are only ten surveys of sufficienttimeliness <strong>and</strong> compatibil<strong>it</strong>y for the whole of the developing <strong>and</strong>trans<strong>it</strong>ion world. This then <strong>mean</strong>s that to get a view of levels <strong>access</strong>across the world requires looking at proxy indicators that have a goodlikelihood of tracking <strong>access</strong> even if they <strong>do</strong> not exactly measure <strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong>this paper attempts to <strong>do</strong> that using two approaches:■■The first is to look at <strong>how</strong> much money there is in an economy <strong>and</strong><strong>how</strong> this spl<strong>it</strong>s between cash <strong>and</strong> depos<strong>it</strong>s. One can be fairly confidentthat <strong>access</strong> is repressed where the total depos<strong>it</strong> base of the bankingsystem is less than 20% of GDP <strong>and</strong> cash in circulation ranges upwardsfrom the equivalent of a third of total depos<strong>it</strong> balances. At the otherextreme an economy is almost certainly approaching full <strong>access</strong> wheredepos<strong>it</strong>-to-GDP ratios are approaching 100% <strong>and</strong> cash in circulation isequivalent to well below 20% of total depos<strong>it</strong> balances (<strong>and</strong> moretypically below 10%).The second approach – piloted by the Consultative Group to Assistthe Poor (CGAP) – is to identify the number of accounts at <strong>access</strong>ibleinst<strong>it</strong>utions specifically targeting their services at the mass market <strong>and</strong>penetrating beyond those customers typically served by commercial<strong>banks</strong>. These inst<strong>it</strong>utions – sometimes known as <strong>do</strong>uble bottom-line oralternative financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions – comprise commun<strong>it</strong>y, co-operative,development <strong>and</strong> <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> as well as cred<strong>it</strong> unions, specialistmicrofinance inst<strong>it</strong>utions (MFIs) <strong>and</strong> commercial bank microcred<strong>it</strong>ingschemes. The sort of people <strong>and</strong> businesses that use these inst<strong>it</strong>utionscan then be described as the market for <strong>access</strong>ible finance. A cr<strong>it</strong>icalmeasure of <strong>how</strong> well this market is supplied is the number of <strong>access</strong>ibleaccounts per adult in each country’s population.1415


This indicator is calculated for almost 120 developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ioneconomies <strong>and</strong> ranked to display the spectrum of experience in thesecountries. It would seem not unreasonable to suggest <strong>access</strong> isrepressed where there is less than one account for every five adults asin such circumstances most families will not include someone w<strong>it</strong>h anaccount. By the time the number of <strong>access</strong>ible accounts per adult isabove 0.5 then an economy is almost certainly approaching full <strong>access</strong>(albe<strong>it</strong> not necessarily there yet) because most households willprobably include someone w<strong>it</strong>h an account.Some 130 developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies can be addressed by atleast one of these two approaches. Overall, the analysis suggests thereare some 1.4 billion <strong>access</strong>ible accounts across the developing <strong>and</strong>trans<strong>it</strong>ion world – at least one <strong>access</strong>ible account for every 2 1 /2 adults,but this average is biased up by a few large countries w<strong>it</strong>h relatively high<strong>access</strong>. Three times more developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies displaysigns of repressed <strong>access</strong> than those that appear to be moving towardsfull <strong>access</strong>.E. Differences in <strong>access</strong> across countries <strong>and</strong> regionsAmong the advanced industrial economies, the detailed survey datasuggest that exclusion is a very small problem in the relatively urbanised,social market economies of Europe (the Sc<strong>and</strong>inavian countries, France,Germany, the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s plus Spain) where <strong>access</strong> runs upwards of95% <strong>and</strong> the same is almost certainly true of Japan. In the middle arewhat might be called the transatlantic market economies of the UK <strong>and</strong>the US (<strong>and</strong> anec<strong>do</strong>tally probably also Australia). Running below theaverage are the more southerly EU states except Spain but plus Irel<strong>and</strong>,where <strong>access</strong> seems to be pulled <strong>do</strong>wn by relatively higher proportions ofrural dwellers among the population <strong>and</strong> the greater regional incomeinequal<strong>it</strong>y that can result from this. This issue of geographic exclusion isnot, <strong>how</strong>ever, exclusive to these countries. There is growing concernthat mainstream commercial <strong>banks</strong> across the developed world areconcentrating their physical reach <strong>and</strong> marketing prior<strong>it</strong>ies on moreprof<strong>it</strong>able customers, such that universal <strong>access</strong> is then only guaranteedby the continued presence of proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> in the less favoured areas.Of the 130 developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies that can be addressedby at least one of the two approaches described in section D above,26 countries appear to be approaching or clearly already have full <strong>access</strong>.Slightly more than this number (30 countries) are in an intermediatephase w<strong>it</strong>h less than half the adult population having an account butprobably up to half of households having some sort of <strong>access</strong>. This leavesmore than half the sample (74 countries) displaying signs of repressed<strong>access</strong>. Using this grading four fairly clear conclusions emerge:■ Sub-Saharan Africa is very far behind most other regions in exp<strong>and</strong>ingfinancial <strong>access</strong>. Much, but by no <strong>mean</strong>s all, of this is a reflection ofthe extremes of poverty seen there.■ Asia is generally very advanced in exp<strong>and</strong>ing financial <strong>access</strong>. This isparticularly true in the more rapidly industrialising countries but alsoapplies to Asia more generally.■ The more advanced trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies of Central Europe haveprogressed extremely well in rebuilding <strong>access</strong> but most CIS countrieslag behind.■ There has been relatively l<strong>it</strong>tle progress made in Central <strong>and</strong> SouthAmerica desp<strong>it</strong>e a relatively robust economic base, particularly amonglarger countries.F. The main constraints in different countries <strong>and</strong> regionsThree main themes emerge from the l<strong>it</strong>erature survey on what constrains<strong>access</strong>. One borne out at least partially by the data analysis is the absenceof basic pre-requis<strong>it</strong>es for monetised exchange, namely proxim<strong>it</strong>y of arelevant bank <strong>and</strong> l<strong>it</strong>eracy. In advanced economies the issue of <strong>access</strong> tobranches is sens<strong>it</strong>ive but of an altogether lower magn<strong>it</strong>ude than problemsw<strong>it</strong>h <strong>access</strong> to branches for the rural poor in developing economies (wherethe nearest branch can be many kilometres away). Moreover questions ofl<strong>it</strong>eracy in advanced economies relate to underst<strong>and</strong>ing the appropriatenessof different financial services whereas in developing countries <strong>it</strong> is oftena matter of being able to read or wr<strong>it</strong>e at all. There seems some linkagebetween the balance of rural versus urban populations <strong>and</strong> assessed<strong>access</strong>ibil<strong>it</strong>y at least for parts of Africa <strong>and</strong> Central & Southern America.It seems probable that the agglomerative returns to the increasedconcentration of populations that <strong>foster</strong>ed the industrial revolution <strong>and</strong>commercialisation of agriculture also drive the deepening of monetisedexchange that is so cr<strong>it</strong>ical to rising efficiency <strong>and</strong> overall economicdevelopment.1617


A second factor constraining <strong>access</strong> is also un<strong>do</strong>ubtedly the cost of bankingservices although this is poorly <strong>do</strong>cumented. It is also subject to thestrange para<strong>do</strong>x that the poor who are excluded from effective use ofbasic banking products often end up paying more to achieve the sameeconomic ends as those apparently unaffordable banking services fromwhich they are excluded. Finally, the legal <strong>and</strong> organisational foundations(civil codes, transparent licensing arrangements, etc) for most economicactiv<strong>it</strong>y outside a h<strong>and</strong>ful of advanced economies (under thirty out of 200+according to some estimates) are just not in place. Increasingly thepragmatic approach needed to deal w<strong>it</strong>h clients operating at the margin offormal economies is coming up against regulatory pressures to conformto international best practice on bank supervision <strong>and</strong> money laundering.G. Public mechanisms for stimulating <strong>access</strong> to financeThree main themes emerge from the l<strong>it</strong>erature survey.■ The first is that trying to m<strong>and</strong>ate <strong>access</strong> works only to a lim<strong>it</strong>ed degreealthough regulatory pressure may help keep the issue on the bankingindustry agenda. For this to work, <strong>how</strong>ever, <strong>it</strong> is important that thecost of regulation <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> not force up the cost of intermediation, whichis one of the main identified barriers to <strong>access</strong>.■ However, the conclusion that governments cannot m<strong>and</strong>ate <strong>access</strong> isnot the same as saying that they cannot stimulate <strong>access</strong> by at leastpaying wages <strong>and</strong> welfare benef<strong>it</strong>s <strong>and</strong> salaries through bank accounts.It seems that one of the biggest contributory factors for self-exclusionis making such payments as cash or through any form of bearermoney-order.■ The third relates to the need to refine inst<strong>it</strong>utional arrangements to try<strong>and</strong> target finance to excluded groups – trad<strong>it</strong>ionally this has taken theform of special lending schemes or inst<strong>it</strong>utions for enterprise <strong>and</strong> thedevelopment of basic banking services through other channels such aspost offices.H. Banking in<strong>it</strong>iatives to maintain <strong>and</strong> improve <strong>access</strong>to financeIn the advanced industrial economies most banking sector responsesoutside the <strong>savings</strong> bank sector (discussed separately in section I) toproblems of household <strong>access</strong> appear to have been reactive to publicpolicy rather than pro-active. In the l<strong>it</strong>erature on <strong>access</strong> this is seen as afeature of the pressures of globalisation <strong>and</strong> <strong>banks</strong>’ desires to sustainshareholder returns in an environment of disinflation, intensifyingcompet<strong>it</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> declining margins – w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>banks</strong> <strong>do</strong>ing the minimum toallay public policy concerns about growing exclusion while pursuingrationalisation of branch networks, marketing prior<strong>it</strong>ies <strong>and</strong> productcross-subsidies. By contrast, interest in schemes to improve <strong>access</strong> tocred<strong>it</strong> for small <strong>and</strong> medium enterprises is strongly established <strong>and</strong>probably becoming stronger as the attractiveness of subsidised fundingbecomes more apparent against a background of falling margins on moregeneral intermediation of retail <strong>savings</strong>.Similar tensions are apparent in developing countries where manymainstream commercial <strong>banks</strong> have reduced branch networks <strong>and</strong>focused on the most prof<strong>it</strong>able areas of their business. There are, <strong>how</strong>ever,many examples of <strong>banks</strong> that have set up successful microfinance un<strong>it</strong>sunder the umbrella of, but clearly distinct from, their mainstream bankingoperations. This allows these microfinance operations to benef<strong>it</strong> fromthe infrastructure <strong>and</strong> control systems of a properly regulated bankingenvironment but still adapt themselves to the real<strong>it</strong>y of dealing w<strong>it</strong>hsmall-scale clients. Typically they focus on microcred<strong>it</strong> but this has oftenbrought w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>it</strong> growing volumes of small-scale <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> transactionbusiness. There is also some evidence that non-bank microcred<strong>it</strong> schemescan transform themselves to more fully-fledged bank-based microfinance.An add<strong>it</strong>ional theme, which will in<strong>it</strong>ially increase self-exclusion but shouldultimately improve <strong>access</strong>, is pressure for increased transparency on the costsof banking services. As already noted one of the para<strong>do</strong>xes of exclusionis that the poor often end up paying more for financial services that theyostensibly cannot afford to purchase from mainstream <strong>banks</strong>. This linksthrough to another topic that has not yet been fully developed w<strong>it</strong>hin thisstudy, namely the need to build financial l<strong>it</strong>eracy <strong>and</strong> educate potentialcustomers on <strong>how</strong> to use <strong>banks</strong> effectively.1819


I. <strong>What</strong> more needs to be <strong>do</strong>ne by the private <strong>and</strong>public sectorThe evidence from the study <strong>and</strong> this brief summary clearly s<strong>how</strong>s that<strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> exclusion are not issues that the banking sector can tacklealone. Again, conclusions are different for poorer developing countries <strong>and</strong>advanced industrial economies but a number of common themes emerge:■ Access is a serious issue <strong>and</strong> <strong>it</strong> needs to be measured far more carefully<strong>and</strong> consistently than at present.Efforts are underway to improve population <strong>and</strong> enterprise survey databut such surveys are expensive <strong>and</strong> can, as a result, often only be <strong>do</strong>neat widely spaced intervals. Mechanisms for collecting supplier data onthe number of depos<strong>it</strong>s taken, loans made <strong>and</strong> transactions processedalso need improving as this can be <strong>do</strong>ne on a more frequent basis thanmarket surveys.■ Because cost is a cr<strong>it</strong>ical barrier to <strong>access</strong>, <strong>it</strong> needs to be addressedbetter in terms of both the transparency of costs to customers <strong>and</strong><strong>how</strong> supervisors view banking system soundness.■ Addressing the issue of l<strong>it</strong>eracy – whether financial l<strong>it</strong>eracy problemsthat lead to exclusion from developed banking services or morefundamental l<strong>it</strong>eracy problems that impede <strong>access</strong> to even the mostbasic services – is not an issue for <strong>banks</strong> alone.■ There also has to be a frank underst<strong>and</strong>ing that in advanced industrialeconomies the direct financial benef<strong>it</strong>s to <strong>banks</strong> of reaching the last10% of potential customers are lim<strong>it</strong>ed. Governments probably havemore at stake in bringing these people into the banking system than<strong>banks</strong> <strong>do</strong> <strong>and</strong> regulation needs to reflect the pragmatic real<strong>it</strong>ies ofdealing w<strong>it</strong>h these marginal segments of the market. Official att<strong>it</strong>udesto social banking need to be adjusted accordingly.■ Exactly the same pragmatic real<strong>it</strong>ies apply regarding outreach to therural poor in much less developed economies – this will not work ifsuch activ<strong>it</strong>ies are subject to ill-considered regulation that raises thecost of rural branch networks <strong>and</strong> bank-based microfinance.J. The role of the <strong>savings</strong> bank movement in developing<strong>access</strong>Some of the most active responses to both public policy in<strong>it</strong>iatives toimprove <strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> the more general problem of maintaining <strong>and</strong>improving <strong>access</strong> come from <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> other socially comm<strong>it</strong>tedretail <strong>banks</strong> across the world. For many of them a comm<strong>it</strong>ment touniversal commun<strong>it</strong>y <strong>access</strong> is wr<strong>it</strong>ten e<strong>it</strong>her into their founding social(<strong>and</strong> sometimes legal) m<strong>and</strong>ate or their mission statements as privatecommun<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong>. As a result, <strong>it</strong> is not really surprising that <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong><strong>and</strong> other socially comm<strong>it</strong>ted retail <strong>banks</strong> are by far the largest identifiedsuppliers of <strong>access</strong>ible accounts across the developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ionworld – accounting for some three-quarters of all such accounts. Even inadvanced economies, these <strong>banks</strong> are often the only mainstream bankingoperations left in areas of geographic exclusion <strong>and</strong> are active in tacklingthe issue of financial ill<strong>it</strong>eracy.This study now makes a strong case that for developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ioneconomies to move towards full <strong>access</strong> needs a strong <strong>savings</strong> bank orother proxim<strong>it</strong>y bank presence. Furthermore, this study suggestsmicrofinance is more of a complement to proxim<strong>it</strong>y banking rather thana subst<strong>it</strong>ute. In add<strong>it</strong>ion, a high degree of social ownership in moreadvanced industrial economies often goes h<strong>and</strong> in h<strong>and</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h heightenedlevels of <strong>access</strong> for both households <strong>and</strong> small <strong>and</strong> medium enterprises.It is misleading to think of all <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> as <strong>savings</strong>-only inst<strong>it</strong>utions– across the developing world non-postal <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> recycle half theirdepos<strong>it</strong>s as cred<strong>it</strong>s. Moreover, average loan sizes for the entire loanportfolios of <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> in South America <strong>and</strong> Central Europe aresimilar to average loan sizes at specialist microcred<strong>it</strong> schemes. It is alsomisleading to think of all <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> as only dealing w<strong>it</strong>h consumers –across the world the dividing line between personal <strong>and</strong> microenterprisefinance is always blurred. In any case, many <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> are particularlyactive in the field of microfinance in developing countries <strong>and</strong> also havea strong historic presence in the market for financial services for small <strong>and</strong>medium enterprises in advanced industrial economies.2021


A common theme across both advanced industrial <strong>and</strong> developingeconomies is the negative impact on <strong>access</strong> coming from tensionsbetween economic development agendas aimed at <strong>foster</strong>ing enterprise<strong>and</strong> reducing poverty, <strong>and</strong> financial policy agendas aimed atst<strong>and</strong>ardising regulation <strong>and</strong> increasing market-based compet<strong>it</strong>ion acrossthe world. There is a para<strong>do</strong>x here. Non-market mechanisms (particularlyinternal cross-subsidisation) often allow <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> other proxim<strong>it</strong>y<strong>banks</strong> to remain in commun<strong>it</strong>ies ab<strong>and</strong>oned by mainstream commercial<strong>banks</strong>. But these same mechanisms are under pressure from compet<strong>it</strong>ionpolicies that take l<strong>it</strong>tle account of the fact these <strong>banks</strong> did not choose tobecome the prevailing <strong>and</strong> sometimes only supplier outside major moneycentres. This is an area that needs both more work <strong>and</strong> attention bypolicy-makers.K. Conclusions■ Access is an important issue but <strong>it</strong> has to be understood differentlyfrom the related issue of exclusion, as the solutions are different.■ The <strong>savings</strong> bank movement has an instinctive sympathy for improving<strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> this study s<strong>how</strong>s <strong>how</strong> important the movement is tosustaining what <strong>access</strong> there already is.■ At newly identified levels of supply, <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> account for threequarters of the 1.4 billion <strong>access</strong>ible accounts provided across developing<strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies.■ Moreover an economy is very unlikely to be approaching full <strong>access</strong>unless <strong>it</strong> has a strong <strong>savings</strong> bank movement or other proxim<strong>it</strong>ybanking presence.■ Regulators need to recognise that the governments they serve mayhave more at stake in improving <strong>access</strong> than commercially run <strong>banks</strong>.Regulation should be fine-tuned accordingly.■ As always the performance of banking systems cannot be understoodin isolation from the system of pol<strong>it</strong>ical economy w<strong>it</strong>hin which theyoperate. Governments are likely to <strong>do</strong> more to improve <strong>access</strong> byimproving the foundations of civil society than by trying to m<strong>and</strong>ate<strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> interfere w<strong>it</strong>h product design.2. THE NATURE OF ACCESS:AN OVERVIEW OFTHE LITERATUREPart One: Introduction <strong>and</strong> the Role of FinanceA. IntroductionIn assembling this review <strong>it</strong> has proved useful to distinguish the l<strong>it</strong>erature,<strong>and</strong> even the language, that relates to low-income developing countriesfrom that relating to advanced industrial economies such as the EuropeanUnion, the USA <strong>and</strong> Japan. This is because <strong>access</strong> to formal financialinst<strong>it</strong>utions is frequently the preserve of a qu<strong>it</strong>e small minor<strong>it</strong>y in lowincomecountries. By contrast <strong>it</strong> is qu<strong>it</strong>e unusual not to have some <strong>access</strong>if you live in a major industrial society.For example, in Kenya which has one of the better financial systems in Africa,only around 3 million (10%) of <strong>it</strong>s 30 million people have some sort ofrelationship w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> other financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions (KIPPRA [2001]).Even in Mexico – a much more urbanised <strong>and</strong> higher income developingcountry – only 20% of the urban population (<strong>and</strong> a much lower proportionof the rural population) have <strong>access</strong> to bank accounts (Solo [2001]). In theadvanced industrial economies, by contrast, the corresponding rates of<strong>access</strong> are typically above 80% <strong>and</strong> in Germany <strong>and</strong> in the Sc<strong>and</strong>inaviancountries this rises to 98-99% (Pesaresi <strong>and</strong> Pilley [2003]).If readers want a simple propos<strong>it</strong>ion to fix the contrasts, they can notethat the percentage rate of <strong>access</strong> in poorer economies is typically aboutequal to the percentage rate of exclusion in those richer countries wherelack of <strong>access</strong> is seen as a problem.Because of these huge numerical differences the debate about <strong>access</strong> tofinancial services tends to be located in different spheres of analysis in thetwo types of countries. In richer countries such as the UK, France <strong>and</strong> the USA,w<strong>it</strong>h a developed l<strong>it</strong>erature on “financial exclusion”, the topic has stronglinks w<strong>it</strong>h the broader debate about “social exclusion” more generally.2223


This is for very good reasons. Many of the same factors that cause certainpeople to get excluded from <strong>access</strong> to jobs, housing, good schools etc.also help explain their poor <strong>access</strong> to financial services (HM Treasury [1999]).Equally, the policy <strong>and</strong> inst<strong>it</strong>utional recommendations needed to enhancefinancial <strong>access</strong> involve relatively broad-based steps to improve thecircumstances of the “excluded” in general terms. Increasingly they havebegun to include explic<strong>it</strong> government policies to extend banking services tothe previously “unbanked” sections of society (Pesaresi <strong>and</strong> Pilley [2003]).By contrast, the issue of financial <strong>access</strong> in low-income countries is anintegral part of the debate about <strong>how</strong> to address widespread poverty.It gets bracketed w<strong>it</strong>h issues of <strong>access</strong> to basic needs such as clean water<strong>and</strong> minimal education <strong>and</strong> above all w<strong>it</strong>h the steps needed to improvethe labour <strong>and</strong> other incomes associated w<strong>it</strong>h productive activ<strong>it</strong>y in largeparts of the economy as a whole (World Bank [2000]).The dichotomy as between “rich” <strong>and</strong> “poor” countries is obviously nota rigid one. Many low-income countries of a generation ago have maderemarkable economic progress <strong>and</strong> now share many of the features ofthe industrialised countries (South Korea, Singapore, Malaysia are goodexamples). Some of these countries are benef<strong>it</strong>ing at an incredibly fastrate from the new banking possibil<strong>it</strong>ies created by electronic technologies(see Claessens [2003]). However, the distinction <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> help to achievesome structure in an otherwise bewildering divers<strong>it</strong>y of l<strong>it</strong>erature.B. Does finance matter <strong>and</strong> if so why?An increasing amount of cross-country empirical research has beenconducted in the past 10 years on this question. This research builds onthe encyclopaedic assembly of data by the pioneer of this topic, RaymondGoldsm<strong>it</strong>h (e.g. Goldsm<strong>it</strong>h [1969]). That research is directly relevant tothe topic of <strong>access</strong> because the question in the t<strong>it</strong>le is normally phrasedin terms of whether a bigger financial system, that provides greatervolumes of cred<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong> mobilises larger volumes of depos<strong>it</strong>s, is a pos<strong>it</strong>iveinfluence on economic development. As always in such studies, the taskof distinguishing cause <strong>and</strong> effect is complex but this has been madeincreasingly possible through the use of improved econometric <strong>and</strong>statistical techniques.However, no one disputes the point that there are many non-financialdevelopments that together help to cause financial development to occur:i.e. that invert the cause-effect relationship. These include: technologicalimprovements such as automatic teller machines <strong>and</strong> electronic bankingthat lower the costs of various financial transactions (Merton [1992] <strong>and</strong>Claessens [2003]); monetary <strong>and</strong> fiscal policies that affect the degree ofimplic<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong> explic<strong>it</strong> taxation of finance (McKinnon [1973], Roubini<strong>and</strong> Sala-i-Martin [1995]; legal changes that impact the attractivenessof certain financial instruments (Laporta et al. [1996]); <strong>and</strong> above alleconomic growth <strong>and</strong> rising living st<strong>and</strong>ards that alter the abil<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong>willingness of people to participate in the financial system (Greenwood<strong>and</strong> Jovanovic [1990]).But these propos<strong>it</strong>ions notw<strong>it</strong>hst<strong>and</strong>ing, there is increasing evidence thatan efficient, broad-based financial system provides a powerful impetusfor economic growth. In modern times Sir John Hicks [1969] hasarticulated this forcefully. He illustrated his point by referring to the keyrole of the financial system in helping to mobilise huge volumes of cap<strong>it</strong>alfor “immense works” during Br<strong>it</strong>ain’s industrial revolution. Much earlier,Joseph Schumpeter [1912] had contended that well-functioning <strong>banks</strong> canspur technological innovation by moving funds to those entrepreneursbest able to undertake innovative processes <strong>and</strong> develop new products.The more recent research supports these basic ideas w<strong>it</strong>h an increasinglysophisticated set of econometric studies.1. The theoryBefore getting into these, let us explore the theoretical basis of thecausative link from financial system development to economic growth.At the purest level, money <strong>and</strong> other financial instruments only existbecause of the need to deal w<strong>it</strong>h the transactions costs <strong>and</strong> problemsof information found in all real world economic systems. A bartereconomy would be perfectly efficient if we could all conduct in-kindtrades at zero transaction costs <strong>and</strong> if everyone w<strong>it</strong>h whom we werelikely to deal was reliable beyond a sha<strong>do</strong>w of <strong>do</strong>ubt. It is the failureof these two “ifs” that render money <strong>and</strong> other financial devicesnecessary (Goodhart [1975]). Extending the logic we can say that asophisticated financial system is one that has found ways to deal w<strong>it</strong>ha wide range of different transaction costs <strong>and</strong> informational problemsthat would otherwise prevent desirable production <strong>and</strong> trading activ<strong>it</strong>iesfrom taking place. Sophisticated “derivative” instruments (e.g. options,swaps, caps) are increasingly enabling economic agents to deal w<strong>it</strong>hthe inherent uncertainties about future events.2425


More generally, by reducing transaction costs <strong>and</strong> m<strong>it</strong>igatinginformational problems, financial systems provide three maincontributions to faster economic growth.First they contribute to a more efficient allocation of resources, acrossboth time <strong>and</strong> space <strong>and</strong> in an uncertain environment (Merton <strong>and</strong>Brodie [1995]). In the absence of an intermediation system (or when <strong>it</strong>is disabled by poor policies such as those of financial repression) saverslargely need to invest their surplus funds in their own projects or inthose of immediate relatives, friends <strong>and</strong> neighbours who they cantrust (Galbis [1977]). The huge gaps, in time <strong>and</strong> space, that weobserve in today’s modern financial systems between <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong>investment decisions, enables savers a far greater choice <strong>and</strong> ensuresthat the available stock of the world’s cap<strong>it</strong>al is used in projects w<strong>it</strong>hthe best possible returns.At least this is a piece of base-line theory that serves us fairly well whenwe confine discussion to <strong>do</strong>mestic financial systems. It is subject togreater challenge when applied to global movements of funds <strong>and</strong> totopics such as whether liberal cap<strong>it</strong>al accounts are desirable, especiallyfor low-income economies. A useful synthesis of the main reservationsabout liberal international cap<strong>it</strong>al can be found in Eichengreen <strong>and</strong>Mussa [1998] <strong>and</strong> more recently in Prasad, Rogoff <strong>and</strong> Kose [2003].A more polemical discussion is in Stigl<strong>it</strong>z [2002]. The cr<strong>it</strong>ical core ofthese newer arguments depends on the informational failuresthat plague transactions between distant countries <strong>and</strong> the inabil<strong>it</strong>y,thus far, for reliable financial instruments to emerge to m<strong>it</strong>igatesuch failures.When we explore the issue of <strong>access</strong> in the <strong>do</strong>mestic setting, we findthat informational problems, <strong>and</strong> the absence of instruments toaddress these, can also explain qu<strong>it</strong>e a lot of the residual difficulties.An example would be the difficulty of minor<strong>it</strong>y ethnic groups gainingthe same <strong>access</strong> to banking services as those enjoyed by a nativeEnglishman, Frenchman or German (example, Kempson <strong>and</strong> Whyley[2000]).Second, the allocative function of finance only works – <strong>do</strong>mestically orinternationally – if the financial system can successfully fulfil <strong>it</strong>s secondmain function. This is the function of mobilising <strong>savings</strong>. Assuming thatthe allocation mechanisms are working tolerably well, then the moreeffective a system is in mobilising <strong>savings</strong>, the higher will be theeconomy-wide rate of return on new investments <strong>and</strong> the faster theeconomy’s rate of growth. Financial systems where the mobilisationfunction is weak will make less contribution to growth irrespective ofthe qual<strong>it</strong>y of the component inst<strong>it</strong>utions.This is one reason why weak <strong>access</strong> to finance is a problem for broadbaseddevelopment. If few people save through <strong>banks</strong>, then there isno raw material for even a good banking system to intermediate.Equally the costs of banking are likely to be raised because of theabsence of economies of scale.Weaknesses in the mobilisation function of a financial system are verycommon in low-income countries. In some such cases, internationalaid <strong>do</strong>nors have tried to compensate by providing funding forDevelopment Finance Companies (DFCs) or Microfinance Inst<strong>it</strong>utions(MFIs) for a short period of years. But when the <strong>do</strong>nor fundingends, the absence of a serious mobilisation role for the inst<strong>it</strong>utionsconcerned will threaten their abil<strong>it</strong>y to survive (Fern<strong>and</strong>o [2003] <strong>and</strong>Section J below).The third key function of finance that explains <strong>it</strong>s pos<strong>it</strong>ive contributionto growth is that of risk m<strong>it</strong>igation. Risks in production <strong>and</strong> trade areubiqu<strong>it</strong>ous <strong>and</strong> are typically compounded when production <strong>and</strong> tradecrosses international boundaries. Categories of risk include cred<strong>it</strong> risk,commercial risk, foreign exchange risk, pol<strong>it</strong>ical risk, <strong>and</strong> liquid<strong>it</strong>y risk.By helping agents engaged in production <strong>and</strong> trade to hedge some ofthese risks, a financial system increases the volume of production <strong>and</strong>trade that is successful <strong>and</strong> prof<strong>it</strong>able. Economic growth is therebyenhanced. A particularly important example of this as far as <strong>banks</strong> areconcerned is what Levine [1996] refers to as “liquid<strong>it</strong>y risk”. This arisesbecause many high return investment projects require that cap<strong>it</strong>al betied up for long periods of time. However, many savers are willing tocomm<strong>it</strong> their funds to <strong>banks</strong> for only a short period of time. But a wellrun commercial or <strong>savings</strong> bank can effect a matur<strong>it</strong>y transformation(i.e. can borrow at short matur<strong>it</strong>ies <strong>and</strong> lend at much longer matur<strong>it</strong>ies).Hence in providing the services of depos<strong>it</strong> mobilisation <strong>and</strong> allocation,a well run bank will also m<strong>it</strong>igate the liquid<strong>it</strong>y risks that woul<strong>do</strong>therwise discourage savers from lending to help finance long-terminvestments.A similar growth-enhancing service is inherent in cap<strong>it</strong>al marketinstruments of various types <strong>and</strong> also in the intermediaries such as lifeinsurance companies <strong>and</strong> mutual trusts that package theseinstruments in order to attract more savers. As the cap<strong>it</strong>al marketinstruments involved in providing this type of risk m<strong>it</strong>igation becomeincreasingly accepted, they can set up an important compet<strong>it</strong>ivechallenge to <strong>banks</strong> who are the trad<strong>it</strong>ional providers of such a service.2627


One final word on risk m<strong>it</strong>igation <strong>and</strong> the important contribution ofthe financial sector to economic growth. Economic historians haveincreasingly argued that technological changes such as those seen inWestern Europe in the 17th <strong>and</strong> 18th century were merely thenecessary cond<strong>it</strong>ions for accelerated economic growth. The furtherdevelopment that enabled this new technological potential to berealised was the financial revolution that enabled the liquid <strong>savings</strong>of thous<strong>and</strong>s of people to be used for the huge but illiquid newinvestments in long-term projects that the industrial revolutionrequired. Friendly Society <strong>and</strong> Savings Bank movements were a majorpart of this financial revolution.2. The modern evidenceGoldsm<strong>it</strong>h started the modern trad<strong>it</strong>ion of data-intensive enquiry onthis topic w<strong>it</strong>h a study of 35 countries (Goldsm<strong>it</strong>h [1969]). This wasreadily cr<strong>it</strong>icised by Goldsm<strong>it</strong>h himself <strong>and</strong> his successors on the groundsthat his result made <strong>it</strong> hard to sort out cause <strong>and</strong> effect. Did financecause growth or was <strong>it</strong> the other way round? A similar commentapplied to the extremely well-known study by McKinnon [1973].This studied the relationship between the financial system <strong>and</strong>development in a small group of mostly middle-income developingcountries, <strong>and</strong> concluded that better financial systems defin<strong>it</strong>elysupported faster economic growth.King <strong>and</strong> Levine [1993] attempted to deal more rigorously w<strong>it</strong>h theproblem of cause <strong>and</strong> effect in an 80-country study (covering the years1960-1989) that systematically controlled for other (i.e. non financialsector) causes of economic growth. They also used a more sophisticatedset of four measures of “financial development”. In relation to all ofthese they found substantial differences between countries w<strong>it</strong>hdifferent levels of income per cap<strong>it</strong>a. In relation to their first measure(a measure of financial depth 1 ), for example they found that c<strong>it</strong>izens ofthe richest quartile of countries held on average two thirds of a year’sincome in formal financial intermediaries whereas their counterparts inthe poorest quartile of countries held only a quarter of their year’s (muchlower) income in the form of liquid financial assets. More importantlythey found a strong pos<strong>it</strong>ive influence from their four financial indicatorson three indicators of economic growth 2 .1 Specifically, currency plus dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> interest bearing liabil<strong>it</strong>ies of <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> NBFIs.2 Long run real per cap<strong>it</strong>a growth, cap<strong>it</strong>al accumulation <strong>and</strong> productiv<strong>it</strong>y growth.The explanatory financial variables were not only statisticallysignificant but also suggested a magn<strong>it</strong>ude of effect (from finance togrowth) of some importance. For example, a rise in financial depthfrom the <strong>mean</strong> of the slowest growing quartile of countries to that ofthe fastest growing quartile could by <strong>it</strong>self eliminate 20% of thedifferences in their growth rates (i.e. one percentage point of the fivepercentage point differences in growth rates seen over the 30-yearperiod of the data).Later studies such as that by Levine <strong>and</strong> Zervos [1998] <strong>and</strong> Beck,Levine <strong>and</strong> Loayza [2001] have elaborated the basic metho<strong>do</strong>logyof King <strong>and</strong> Levine by refining the metho<strong>do</strong>logy for dealing w<strong>it</strong>hsimultane<strong>it</strong>y; by making use of better qual<strong>it</strong>y data on private <strong>savings</strong>across countries (due to Loayza, Lopez, Schmidt-Hebbel <strong>and</strong> Serven [1998]);<strong>and</strong> by invoking improved measures of banking depth. The latter paperrelates mainly to some 63 countries w<strong>it</strong>h data covering the period1960-1995. The authors found that higher levels of bankingdevelopment produced faster rates of economic growth <strong>and</strong> highertotal factor productiv<strong>it</strong>y growth in the sample countries. These resultswere also robust to marginal changes in the measures of bankingsector development. However, their results also suggest that theallocative effects of finance may be more important than thequant<strong>it</strong>ative effects working through higher <strong>savings</strong> rates <strong>and</strong> higherlevels of investment.Research at World Bank (Beck, Demirguc-Kunt <strong>and</strong> Martinez Peria[2005]) is now beginning to look directly at the link between economicdevelopment <strong>and</strong> indicators of <strong>access</strong> (branches/ATMs/depos<strong>it</strong>s/loansper head of population <strong>and</strong> average depos<strong>it</strong>/loan balances relative toper-cap<strong>it</strong>a GDP). They also look at links between <strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> enterpriseperceptions of their financing constraint. Provisional results – based onsurveys of regulatory data in 99 countries but not all of which supplieda full data set – indicate “greater outreach is correlated w<strong>it</strong>h st<strong>and</strong>ardmeasures of financial development, as well as w<strong>it</strong>h economic activ<strong>it</strong>y”.This therefore suggests that broadening the client base of a bankingsystem not surprisingly helps deepen <strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong> therefore helps growth.W<strong>it</strong>hin this effect, better communication <strong>and</strong> transport infrastructure,<strong>and</strong> better governance are also associated w<strong>it</strong>h greater outreach,whereas government ownership of financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions translates intolower <strong>access</strong>, but more concentrated banking systems are notassociated w<strong>it</strong>h poorer outreach. Finally, firms in countries w<strong>it</strong>h higherbranch <strong>and</strong> ATM penetration <strong>and</strong> higher use of loan services reportlower financing obstacles, thus linking banking sector outreach to thealleviation of firms’ financing constraints.2829


The conclusion on the impact of government ownership cuts acrossthe results of this study, which finds that <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> – many ofthem publicly-owned – supply the vast bulk of <strong>access</strong>ible accountsto be found in developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies. The differentconclusions may well reflect differences in country <strong>and</strong> inst<strong>it</strong>utionalcoverage. Almost half the <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> in the countries for which Becket al have data are almost certainly excluded because they lie outsidethe regulated depos<strong>it</strong>-money banking system. More importantly 70%of all developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economy <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> – accountingfor half of all <strong>access</strong>ible accounts across the developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ioneconomy world – are in countries not captured by their database.Part Two: Exclusion in Richer CountriesC. The scale of individual financial exclusion in richercountriesAs already noted, financial <strong>access</strong> in the advanced industrial economiestends to average around 90%, w<strong>it</strong>h a variation of around 10 percentagepoints e<strong>it</strong>her side of this average. At the top end of the spectrum are therelatively urbanised, social market economies of Europe (the Sc<strong>and</strong>inaviancountries, France, Germany <strong>and</strong> the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s plus Spain) where <strong>access</strong>runs upwards of 90%. The same is almost certainly true of Japan butno direct data have yet been found for that country. In all these countriesa strong infrastructure for financial <strong>access</strong> built about a well-defined<strong>savings</strong> bank movement has long existed. In the middle are what mightbe called the transatlantic market economies of the UK <strong>and</strong> US (<strong>and</strong>anec<strong>do</strong>tally probably also Australia 3 although again no firm estimateshave been found yet). Running below the average are the more southerlyEU states apart from Spain but add<strong>it</strong>ionally also Irel<strong>and</strong>, where <strong>access</strong>seems to be pulled <strong>do</strong>wn by relatively higher proportions of rural dwellersamong the population <strong>and</strong> the greater regional income inequal<strong>it</strong>y that canresult from this (particularly in the case of Italy - Pesaresi <strong>and</strong> Pilley [2003]).3 A study of the issues involved in financial exclusion in Australia by Connolly <strong>and</strong> Hajaj[2001] provides no national evidence but <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> include case study evidence of exclusionrates of around 10% in deprived urban areas plus un-quantified but not-insignificant ruralexclusion.The table below provides more detail of differences in the current level ofindividual <strong>access</strong> between countries.Table 1: Availabil<strong>it</strong>y of a personal current account, giro accountor similarCountry % of Population Country % of PopulationDenmark 99.1 Spain 91.6Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 98.9 US 91.0Sweden 98.0 UK 87.7Finl<strong>and</strong> 96.7 Portugal 81.6Germany 96.5 Austria 81.4France 96.3 Irel<strong>and</strong> 79.6Luxembourg 94.1 Greece 78.9Belgium 92.7 Italy 70.4EU 15 average 89.6Source: Reproduced from Pesaresi <strong>and</strong> Pilley [2003] w<strong>it</strong>h US added (taken from Caskey [2002])There is, <strong>how</strong>ever, evidence, in Germany <strong>and</strong> some other higher <strong>access</strong>countries in the EU, of the retreat of <strong>banks</strong> from certain regions –especially rural <strong>and</strong> under-populated regions <strong>and</strong> urban areas w<strong>it</strong>heconomic difficulties. This spreads the “geographic exclusion” seen inless urbanised southerly European states. It points to a basic regionalvariation in <strong>access</strong> across regions of the same country w<strong>it</strong>h gaps that maybe widening in some cases. The continued existence of <strong>banks</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h asocial m<strong>and</strong>ate such as the <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> cooperative <strong>banks</strong> in Germanyserves for the time being to m<strong>it</strong>igate the effects of this on <strong>access</strong>.However, such m<strong>it</strong>igation is assured ne<strong>it</strong>her in the long-term nor ingeneral as the tendency for more consolidation of <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> pressures towork on a pan-European scale both intensify. The same issues areidentified in Connolly <strong>and</strong> Hajaj [2001] as applying in Australia, w<strong>it</strong>hmainstream <strong>banks</strong> moving out of poorer urban areas thereby triggeringthe w<strong>it</strong>hdrawal of other economic agents. They also highlight a trend forw<strong>it</strong>hdrawal out of the remote rural commun<strong>it</strong>ies leaving some 600 ofthese w<strong>it</strong>hout any day-to-day <strong>access</strong> to banking services. In contrast toGermany there is no bedrock of socially m<strong>and</strong>ated <strong>banks</strong> in Australia totake up the slack left by the departure of the mainstream <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong>attempts to create a new alternative – so called Rural Transaction Centres– have been very disappointing.3031


A final <strong>and</strong> more subtle aspect of the emerging tendencies as regards<strong>access</strong> relates to Financial L<strong>it</strong>eracy. As we have seen above, problems ofl<strong>it</strong>eral <strong>access</strong> to finance in most rich industrial economies are on arelatively lim<strong>it</strong>ed scale. However, regulatory author<strong>it</strong>ies in both the UK<strong>and</strong> the US plus various social research inst<strong>it</strong>utions in Germany <strong>and</strong>France have drawn attention to a widening gap between the abundanceof ever more diversified <strong>and</strong> sophisticated financial services on the oneh<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the intellectual capac<strong>it</strong>y of the mass market to fully underst<strong>and</strong><strong>and</strong> make good use of these. Financial ill<strong>it</strong>eracy can certainly lead to theself-exclusion of some people from <strong>access</strong> to some products. In othercases <strong>it</strong> can result in consumers making wrong <strong>and</strong> irrational decisionsabout their choice of products <strong>and</strong> in their greater exposure to increasedrisks of fraud <strong>and</strong> theft.Box 1: Financial l<strong>it</strong>eracy <strong>and</strong> the impact on <strong>access</strong>Government agencies as well as private NGOs in industrial richercountries are engaged in a plethora of in<strong>it</strong>iatives to boost thefinancial l<strong>it</strong>eracy, <strong>and</strong> end the self-exclusion of especially theiryounger <strong>and</strong> more vulnerable populations.The Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y (FSA) in the UK typifies the reasonsfor this by stating: ”Consumer education is a key part of consumerprotection, <strong>and</strong> we aim to help consumers make informed choices<strong>and</strong> manage their finances better. Consumer education should alsolead to more compet<strong>it</strong>ion in financial services markets by increasingconsumer pressure. This should in turn encourage innovation, betterqual<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> better value for money.”Here are just a few examples from many <strong>do</strong>zen that currently operate:■■■The National En<strong>do</strong>wment for Financial Education (NEFE) is afoundation dedicated to helping all Americans acquire theinformation <strong>and</strong> gain the skills necessary to take control of theirpersonal finances. NEFE accomplishes <strong>it</strong>s mission primarily bypartnering w<strong>it</strong>h other concerned organizations to providefinancial education particularly to under-served individuals whosefinancial education needs are not being addressed by others.The National Center on Poverty Law has developed a FinancialLinks for Low Income People in<strong>it</strong>iative that offers financial l<strong>it</strong>eracyclasses <strong>and</strong> helps participants set up <strong>savings</strong> accounts atparticipating financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions. Those who complete the classes<strong>and</strong> make depos<strong>it</strong>s every month are eligible for matching money.Asset Builders of America is a non-prof<strong>it</strong> organization, sponsoredby a group of <strong>banks</strong> in Wisconsin that promotes financial l<strong>it</strong>eracyfor people of all ages. It provides day-long seminars <strong>and</strong> weeklysessions for middle school <strong>and</strong> high school students, as well asadult learning seminars that cover basic to more advancedfinancial topics.Because, <strong>how</strong>ever, these are disconnected in<strong>it</strong>iatives w<strong>it</strong>h varyingforms of mission statement, <strong>it</strong> is extremely hard to evaluate theiroverall success in improving <strong>access</strong>. But <strong>it</strong> seems certain at least inthe case of the US that their effect is non trivial.Chapter 5 also describes various in<strong>it</strong>iatives by European <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong>to address this cr<strong>it</strong>ical issue.A study of financial l<strong>it</strong>eracy in Australia was a major recommendationof the recent Australian Stocktake of Consumer Education inFinancial Services undertaken for the Australian Secur<strong>it</strong>ies <strong>and</strong>Investments Commission, which already lists “improving financiall<strong>it</strong>eracy for adults” as one of <strong>it</strong>s prior<strong>it</strong>ies.The s<strong>it</strong>uation in the USA provides probably the most completeexample of the potential content <strong>and</strong> scope of financial education<strong>and</strong> l<strong>it</strong>eracy programmes.3233


D. Causes of improving <strong>access</strong>Recent in-depth studies suggest a strongly rising long-term trend for theproportion of the populations of richer countries having at least a currentbanking account of some description. In the UK, for example, only 45%of adults had a current bank account in 1975 but by 1998 this figure hadrisen to between 80-85%. In the USA, the rise continued through the1990s from some 80-88% of the population in 1994 to 91% by 1998.This trend is repeated across EU countries where the proportion of thepopulation w<strong>it</strong>h a bank account has also risen in line w<strong>it</strong>h increases inwelfare levels.The first <strong>and</strong> most important set of factors explaining improved <strong>access</strong>over these longer periods have been the sustained rises in incomes <strong>and</strong>living st<strong>and</strong>ards in most industrial countries in the past 25 years, combinedw<strong>it</strong>h the growing tendency for more women to work <strong>and</strong> thereby havetheir own incomes <strong>and</strong> <strong>savings</strong> potential. This general rise in prosper<strong>it</strong>yhas been re-enforced in many industrial countries by fiscal reforms thathave seen a smaller tax-take from personal incomes at least in the formof direct taxes.This general tendency also connects w<strong>it</strong>h the evidence from US, UK <strong>and</strong>other European survey research that s<strong>how</strong>s important links between<strong>savings</strong>, income levels <strong>and</strong> personal/family circumstances. Amongst verylow-income households in the UK (less that £150 per week) 60% werew<strong>it</strong>hout <strong>savings</strong> at all as compared to around 30% in the population asa whole (Kempson [1998]). Low levels of disposable income are also foundto be strongly linked w<strong>it</strong>h being a non-saver (McKay [1992]) <strong>and</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h lowlevel of financial wealth (Rowington [1999]). In the US, survey findingsalso s<strong>how</strong> that the un-banked are disproportionately represented in thelower-income households (Caskey [2002]). Similarly, family circumstance<strong>and</strong> especially employment status seem to be cr<strong>it</strong>ical determining factors:the unemployed <strong>and</strong> those not working for reasons of illness or disabil<strong>it</strong>yare very low savers. Kempson [1998] noted this <strong>and</strong> also the effects on<strong>savings</strong> associated w<strong>it</strong>h social class. Those in UK social classes C1/C2(mass-middle), D (lower-end employed) <strong>and</strong> E (welfare dependent) areparticularly low savers. However, this needs to be put in context w<strong>it</strong>h thehigh degree of mobil<strong>it</strong>y found today in both the US <strong>and</strong> the UK.Specifically, there is significant income mobil<strong>it</strong>y in both societies <strong>and</strong> thepeople in the poorest tenth of the population in one year may notnecessarily occupy the same lowest incomes cohort in the next year.The conclusions to this point are those that one would expect. Access tofinancial services is linked to the abil<strong>it</strong>y to save <strong>and</strong> this in turn rises in linew<strong>it</strong>h disposable incomes <strong>and</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>access</strong> to employment. High levels ofincome inequal<strong>it</strong>y have also been argued to be important. (Pesaresi <strong>and</strong>Pilley [2003])Second, there is an important set of explanations that relate to theincreasing de-regulation of financial services (in most industrial countries)<strong>and</strong> the associated increase in compet<strong>it</strong>ion between providers. Leyshon<strong>and</strong> Thrift [1993] have traced this general development to the global level<strong>and</strong> especially to the impact of the international debt crisis that began in1982. This they claimed caused many <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> some non-bank financialintermediaries (NBFIs) to w<strong>it</strong>hdraw at least temporarily from theirinternational markets <strong>and</strong> seek new national markets in their place. Butthere were also specific local <strong>and</strong> <strong>do</strong>mestic factors that accentuated thisincreased compet<strong>it</strong>ion in the <strong>do</strong>mestic financial markets.For example, <strong>and</strong> especially in the USA, the strong acceleration ofcompet<strong>it</strong>ion in banking from the late 1980s was part of the so-called“disintermediation” process. New technologies combined w<strong>it</strong>h changesin the patterns of <strong>savings</strong> behaviour made <strong>it</strong> increasingly possible forvarious NBFIs to offer competing products, especially to larger corporateborrowers. We refer to the rapid growth of the bond <strong>and</strong> derivativesmarkets <strong>and</strong> to savers’ increasing propens<strong>it</strong>y to prefer illiquid cap<strong>it</strong>almarket instruments offered by pension funds <strong>and</strong> other parties totrad<strong>it</strong>ional liquid investment outlets (see Warburton [1999] for anaccount <strong>and</strong> cr<strong>it</strong>ique of these trends). Disintermediation put pressure onbank prof<strong>it</strong>s at the same time as the <strong>banks</strong>’ cost advantages in mobilisingfunds (liabil<strong>it</strong>ies) were being squeezed by compet<strong>it</strong>ion. This provoked bothan increasing search for cost economies of scale <strong>and</strong> scope <strong>and</strong> efforts topackage banking services in more st<strong>and</strong>ardised <strong>and</strong> lower-cost packages(sometimes referred to as “commod<strong>it</strong>isation”). Similar tendencies areevident in the European countries w<strong>it</strong>h strong NBFI sectors.In the UK, the de-regulation of financial services from the 1980s onwardsbroke <strong>do</strong>wn trad<strong>it</strong>ional barriers between sectors of the market (as in theUS) <strong>and</strong> also removed barriers to entry. This led to what has been termedthe “financial supermarket” model of provision of which Richard Branson’sVirgin group is the most well-known proponent (see Lynch <strong>and</strong> Haidar[1998]).3435


Both savers <strong>and</strong> borrowers benef<strong>it</strong>ed from this surge of increased compet<strong>it</strong>ionbecause <strong>it</strong> necess<strong>it</strong>ated old <strong>and</strong> new financial organisations embarking onan ever more intense search for new customers. As Leyson <strong>and</strong> Thrift[1995] put <strong>it</strong> for the UK, “More people than ever before were drawn tothe financial services system …. Nowhere was off-lim<strong>it</strong>s ….. the systembegan to reach into nooks <strong>and</strong> crannies of the Br<strong>it</strong>ish social fabric which<strong>it</strong> had previously shunned.”However, Pesaresi <strong>and</strong> Pilley [2003] from the EU Directorate of Compet<strong>it</strong>iongive one convincing argument running in the oppos<strong>it</strong>e direction. They pointout that in the past in Europe, 80% of current accounts used to be lossmakingbut were financed by the remaining 20% that were prof<strong>it</strong>ablethanks to large average balances. This cross-subsidisation has ceased tobe possible now that banking has become much more aggressivelycompet<strong>it</strong>ive. Other dimensions of increasing cost pressure on <strong>banks</strong> areillustrated in a major recent review of E-banking by Claessens, Glaessner<strong>and</strong> Kingebiel [2003]. They produced estimates for 34 countries of theimpact of the new technologies on bank interest margins from 1997through 2010. Attention is drawn to the very large reductions thatseem likely to be provoked by the greater compet<strong>it</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> lower costsassociated w<strong>it</strong>h E-technologies. This is especially true in some of theemerging market economies such as Brazil <strong>and</strong> Turkey where interestmargins today are extremely high at least by EU st<strong>and</strong>ards.Increased compet<strong>it</strong>ion among <strong>banks</strong> has also been seen in other regionsof the world. For example, in a 10-country study of bank consolidation inEastern Europe <strong>and</strong> the Former Soviet Union by the authors, <strong>it</strong> was foundthat the growth of provision of cred<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong> other services to the SME sectorwas much faster in those countries where more genuine compet<strong>it</strong>ion inbanking had been established (Roe, Peachey et al. [2003]). Pol<strong>and</strong> was aleading example <strong>and</strong> contrasted sharply w<strong>it</strong>h Russia where bankingcompet<strong>it</strong>ion remains weak. In Pol<strong>and</strong>, where SME activ<strong>it</strong>y has grown from30% of GDP in 1995 to 55% in 2001, the <strong>banks</strong> now provide 52.6% oftheir corporate lending to the SME sector <strong>and</strong> attract almost 50% of theircorporate depos<strong>it</strong>s from that source. Estonia is another country w<strong>it</strong>h veryeffective compet<strong>it</strong>ion in banking where SME activ<strong>it</strong>y is high <strong>and</strong> bankloans to SMEs represent a large portion of banking business.Third <strong>and</strong> an important cause of the enhanced compet<strong>it</strong>ion is the greaterinternationalisation of the provision of financial services. This isparticularly important in the area of the European Union where theFinancial Services directives make <strong>it</strong> increasingly difficult for nation statesto maintain serious barriers e<strong>it</strong>her to new entry from fellow EU countriesor to increased compet<strong>it</strong>ion in financial services more generally.E. Characteristics of excluded individualsIn most of the advanced relatively urbanised social market economiesdescribed above, exclusion is not a problem <strong>and</strong> there is, as a result,apparently 4 no substantive l<strong>it</strong>erature on the subject. The emerging l<strong>it</strong>eraturein France (<strong>and</strong> indeed the policy responses – see Chapters 4 <strong>and</strong> 5) haslargely focused on the lim<strong>it</strong>ations placed by poor <strong>access</strong> on the creationof self-employment opportun<strong>it</strong>ies rather than the underlying processof individual exclusion <strong>it</strong>self. This is now changing w<strong>it</strong>h the work ofGloukoviezoff [2004] addressing reasons for individual exclusion <strong>and</strong>at least as importantly self-exclusion. There is also some lim<strong>it</strong>ed presscomment in Spain.The most substantial l<strong>it</strong>erature on individual exclusion relates to the UK<strong>and</strong> USA, in some ways reflecting their pos<strong>it</strong>ioning as outliers in thetaxonomy developed above – both are highly industrialised <strong>and</strong> urbanisedeconomies but w<strong>it</strong>h lower levels of <strong>access</strong> than would be typical of sucheconomies.In the UK, the Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y [2003] used a variety of surveyevidence to develop the following propos<strong>it</strong>ions:■■Non-account holding (i.e. people w<strong>it</strong>hout current accounts w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>banks</strong>or building societies) is concentrated among people w<strong>it</strong>h low incomesor those on income support. Depending on the type of survey, thisfigure is estimated at between 6% <strong>and</strong> 9% of the population. In partthe link between the non-banked <strong>and</strong> welfare dependence is afunction of <strong>how</strong> the Br<strong>it</strong>ish system pays welfare benef<strong>it</strong>s (although thisis now changing). The German system of payment through <strong>banks</strong>, forexample, results in far less exclusion from banking for those who aredependent on welfare.Women are less likely to hold accounts in their own name, althoughthis can be explained by lower incomes <strong>and</strong> personal circumstances, asopposed to gender alone. Account holding amongst people of Pakistani<strong>and</strong> Bangladeshi origin in the UK is disproportionately low, <strong>and</strong> women inthis population group are particularly poorly represented. Accountholding is lowest amongst people under 20 years <strong>and</strong> over 80 years.4 The basis for this statement is the lack of any cross-referencing in academic papers ofmajor bodies of work on individual exclusion outside that undertaken in the Englishspeakingindustrial economies. That no references should appear in e<strong>it</strong>her this l<strong>it</strong>erature oreven recent French-language l<strong>it</strong>erature suggests this is not just a problem of the linguisticcapac<strong>it</strong>y of the researchers involved.3637


The reasons for not having a bank or building society account are varied.There are two basic types of people who <strong>do</strong> not have an account: thosewho have disengaged from banking, <strong>and</strong> those who have never had abank account. Amongst the latter group the reasons for not having abank account include never having needed one <strong>and</strong> instead only using a<strong>savings</strong> account; women relying on their husb<strong>and</strong>s accounts; womenwho become single mothers at a very young age <strong>and</strong> younger peoplewho are yet to open an account. Barriers posed by language, culture,levels of knowledge <strong>and</strong> religion are an important issue that may preventpeople from opening accounts. A small minor<strong>it</strong>y <strong>do</strong> not open accountsdue to their inabil<strong>it</strong>y to provide (increasingly dem<strong>and</strong>ing) proofs ofident<strong>it</strong>y or address or due to their not being judged sufficiently cred<strong>it</strong>worthy for a conventional current account. Lack of geographical <strong>access</strong>to a bank branch is also a factor that several studies have c<strong>it</strong>ed as a factor<strong>and</strong> this is probably the most significant new dimension of the problem.Reduced over-the-counter <strong>access</strong> (caused by bank <strong>and</strong> post-office branchclosures) has been a major factor bringing the exclusion debate to thefore in Sweden, Belgium, France <strong>and</strong> Germany as well as in the UK(Pesaresi <strong>and</strong> Pilley [2003]).The volume of non-use of <strong>savings</strong> products in <strong>banks</strong> or building societiesis rather higher. The reasons for exclusion in this case are usually base<strong>do</strong>n self-exclusion, rather than direct exclusion by providers. People may bedeterred by the fairly high minimum amounts required to open some<strong>savings</strong> accounts. A lack of knowledge about <strong>savings</strong> products is alsoinfluential as a deterrent. Closures of bank <strong>and</strong> building society branchesare making <strong>it</strong> more difficult <strong>and</strong> inconvenient for people to gain physical<strong>access</strong> to a formal method of saving if they are averse to electronictechnologies. The issue of affordabil<strong>it</strong>y plays the biggest influential factorbecause the amounts that people can afford to save seem to determinewhether <strong>savings</strong> are made formally or informally. The difficulty that somemigrant commun<strong>it</strong>ies have encountered in trying to <strong>access</strong> formal <strong>savings</strong>products on arrival in Br<strong>it</strong>ain is also a factor that may have encouragedthe establishment of their own informal <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> loans organisations.As regards the <strong>access</strong> to cred<strong>it</strong>, recent years have seen a particularly rapidgrowth in the range of consumer cred<strong>it</strong> products available in the UK.In add<strong>it</strong>ion the intense compet<strong>it</strong>ion for cred<strong>it</strong> products has <strong>mean</strong>t thatcred<strong>it</strong> is available to a relatively wide customer base. This rapid increasehas <strong>mean</strong>t that the use of cred<strong>it</strong> is now the norm rather than an exception.The major<strong>it</strong>y of households have <strong>access</strong> to major cred<strong>it</strong> facil<strong>it</strong>ies such ascred<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong> store cards, unsecured personal loans or hire purchase agreements(Office of Fair Trading). Only 33% of UK households use no mainstreamcred<strong>it</strong> facil<strong>it</strong>ies.38Measuring the number of people excluded from cred<strong>it</strong> facil<strong>it</strong>ies is difficultgiven that not everyone w<strong>it</strong>hout cred<strong>it</strong> e<strong>it</strong>her needs or wants <strong>it</strong> – 29% ofthose w<strong>it</strong>hout any form of cred<strong>it</strong> said that this was due to an oppos<strong>it</strong>ionto borrowing. People unable to <strong>access</strong> mainstream cred<strong>it</strong> facil<strong>it</strong>ies fall intotwo main groups: people w<strong>it</strong>h poor cred<strong>it</strong> records or a history of bad debtwho will turn to “non-status” lenders to fulfil their cred<strong>it</strong> needs; <strong>and</strong>people living on low incomes who may have to look beyond mainstreamcred<strong>it</strong> provision altogether. Often examining the number of moneylenders<strong>and</strong> pawn-breakers in an area is sufficient to underst<strong>and</strong> the extent ofexclusion from mainstream cred<strong>it</strong> facil<strong>it</strong>ies.Non-status lending markets comprise financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions that caterspecifically to people for whom mainstream lending would be su<strong>it</strong>ablebut who have an insufficient cred<strong>it</strong> rating to <strong>access</strong> them. They operatein similar ways but provide cred<strong>it</strong> at a much higher (even usurious) costto cover the risks associated w<strong>it</strong>h their customer base. Other inst<strong>it</strong>utionscan specifically target the vulnerable group <strong>and</strong> encourage them to takeout loans they are unable to repay.Box 2: How the vulnerable acquire cred<strong>it</strong> in the UKThe Guardian newspaper correspondent Polly Toynbee spent severalmonths living as a penniless single mother in one of the worsecouncil house areas in Lon<strong>do</strong>n. This is <strong>how</strong> she went about buying abed for her welfare-provided apartment.“I found the store on the ground floor of the Elephant <strong>and</strong> Castleshopping centre. Amid all the shabbiness, Crazy George’s emporiumstood out as a gleaming beacon filled w<strong>it</strong>h br<strong>and</strong> new furn<strong>it</strong>ure <strong>and</strong>electrical goods all bathed in gl<strong>it</strong>tering light. On the counter are theCrazy George’s catalogues w<strong>it</strong>h this message: ‘Discover AffordableShopping Made easy!’ Inside <strong>it</strong> promises, ‘All our products are availablew<strong>it</strong>h NO DEPOSIT AND NO CREDIT CHECKS. All the prices arequoted at the per-week hire-purchase price in bold letters. The totalprice in cash is in small letters underneath, because people <strong>do</strong>n’tcome here to pay cash. The cheapest <strong>do</strong>uble bed they offered was abasic metal-barred number. It cost £4.99 per week for 156 weeks –three years. I was not convinced <strong>it</strong> would last that long.39


Even smaller print said ‘Mattress available separately’, w<strong>it</strong>h no mentionof what the mattress cost extra. Further small print said the bed costan astounding £432.38 cash, w<strong>it</strong>hout mattress. … But I could seewhy <strong>it</strong> was tempting to shop this way. However much better <strong>it</strong> wouldbe for me to buy the bed from the remnant of my social fund, I justdid not have that much money <strong>and</strong> could not borrow <strong>it</strong> fromanywhere else. I could see <strong>how</strong> easy <strong>it</strong> was to persuade myself thata mere £4.99 per week was affordable, in my circumstances…… At the back of the catalogue there is a list of places w<strong>it</strong>h CrazyGeorge branches, ninety-five of them in all, w<strong>it</strong>h more to open soon.The list reads like a roll call of the country’s most deprived areas:Birkenhead, Bradford, Burnley, Byker, Corby, Doncaster, Easterhouse,East Ham, Greenock, etc., etc. Wherever there is a Starbucks, aWaterstones, a Jigsaw or a Hab<strong>it</strong>at you can bet there isn’t a CrazyGeorge’s nearby.Polly Toybnee, Hard Work: Life in Low-Pay Br<strong>it</strong>ain, Bloomsbury,Lon<strong>do</strong>n, 2003The reasons for people not having cred<strong>it</strong> are varied. The vast major<strong>it</strong>y ofpeople borrowing from non-status lenders are simply unable to <strong>access</strong>mainstream sources of cred<strong>it</strong> – see the box above. Indiscriminate lendingin the 1980s followed by the recession in the 1990s led to many havingpoor cred<strong>it</strong> records <strong>and</strong> bad debt histories. Mainstream lenders havetightened their lending cr<strong>it</strong>eria <strong>and</strong> their more rigid cred<strong>it</strong> scoring cr<strong>it</strong>eria<strong>mean</strong>s that those w<strong>it</strong>h poor debt histories find <strong>it</strong> very difficult to <strong>access</strong>cred<strong>it</strong>. In add<strong>it</strong>ion, many in this group are attempting to borrow to payexisting debts <strong>and</strong> are unable to borrow from mainstream lendersbecause they have reached or exceeded their cred<strong>it</strong> lim<strong>it</strong> from suchsources. Non-status lenders may be disreputable due to paying very l<strong>it</strong>tleattention to their borrower’s abil<strong>it</strong>y to repay a loan as long as <strong>it</strong> is secure<strong>do</strong>n the customer’s property. Widespread media advertising helps nonstatuslenders attract new business particularly as they encourage peopleto borrow as a way to reduce <strong>and</strong> simplify existing debt repayments.Some groups who are excluded from the mainstream cred<strong>it</strong> marketchoose to turn to alternative lenders due to the easy, quick <strong>and</strong> nonbureaucratic<strong>access</strong>, simple, straight-forward <strong>and</strong> transparent products<strong>and</strong> no hidden charges, penalties <strong>and</strong> defaults.Similar results emerge from a major survey of the un-banked in Los Angeles<strong>and</strong> New York carried out in 1998 by the OCC (Office of the Comptrollerfor Currency – part of the US system of financial <strong>and</strong> monetary control)<strong>and</strong> quoted in detail in Caskey, Ruíz Durán <strong>and</strong> Solo [2004] 5 . The OCCsurvey allowed detailed comparisons of the social, economic <strong>and</strong>demographic profile of the banked <strong>and</strong> un-banked. These s<strong>how</strong>ed theun-banked generally being younger, less educated, renting more <strong>and</strong>working less, w<strong>it</strong>h significantly lower incomes <strong>and</strong> a very much lowerpropens<strong>it</strong>y to save as a result. The Caskey, Ruíz Durán <strong>and</strong> Solo studygoes on to s<strong>how</strong> differences in <strong>how</strong> the banked <strong>and</strong> un-banked pay bills<strong>and</strong> receive income <strong>and</strong> Caskey, drawing on earlier research of his, goeson to s<strong>how</strong> the resulting extra cost to the un-banked of managing theirday-to-day financial settlements in this way. He comes up w<strong>it</strong>h anestimate that a household on $20,000 take-home per year would pay$600 of this (or 3% of income) on payment services, which is at least sixtimes what <strong>it</strong> would cost to use a bank account for the same operationsif <strong>it</strong> could be kept in funds. Similar premiums on the cost of cred<strong>it</strong> takenby the un-banked are s<strong>how</strong>n as are apparent in the UK surveys.Connolly <strong>and</strong> Hajaj [2001], highlighting the lack of real research onthe un-banked in Australia, suggest the following groups are particularlyvulnerable:■ regional <strong>and</strong> remote commun<strong>it</strong>ies■ urban depressed commun<strong>it</strong>ies■ low income consumers■ older consumers■ consumers from non-English speaking backgrounds■ consumers w<strong>it</strong>h disabil<strong>it</strong>ies■ consumers w<strong>it</strong>h l<strong>it</strong>eracy difficulties■ indigenous consumers.5 The paper compares unbanked populations in the US <strong>and</strong> Mexico.4041


F. Access for enterprises – microcred<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong> small businesslendingSmall businesses are acknowledged to be crucial for the growth of anymodern economy. Every year approximately 2 million enterprises are startedup in the EU countries <strong>and</strong> 90% of these are small businesses w<strong>it</strong>h fewerthan five employees.In general there is no l<strong>it</strong>erature suggesting significant exclusion from<strong>access</strong> to depos<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong> payments services for micro, small <strong>and</strong> mediumenterprises, although in the UK there are complaints about the high costof such services – costs that in effect cross-subsidise free personal banking.The other area of concern is that micro-enterprises started up by thoseexcluded from personal banking services are almost by defin<strong>it</strong>ionexcluded from business banking services.Small business entrepreneurs are, <strong>how</strong>ever, widely perceived as facingparticular barriers when attempting to gain <strong>access</strong> to sources of externalfinance to support fixed cap<strong>it</strong>al investment <strong>and</strong> working cap<strong>it</strong>al needs.But evidence from Observatory of European SMEs <strong>and</strong> supporting EuropeanNetwork for Social <strong>and</strong> Economic Research (ENSR) survey data that tracksSME development for the European Commission Enterprise Directorate(EIM Business <strong>and</strong> Policy Research [2004] 6 ), suggests that this is notparticularly a problem of <strong>access</strong> to bank lending:■ less than 20% of those respondents identifying a major constraint togrowth select <strong>access</strong> to finance in <strong>it</strong>s broadest sense as that constraint;■ only about 12% of micro-enterprises, 10% of small enterprises <strong>and</strong>6% of medium-sized firms express dissatisfaction w<strong>it</strong>h the bankingservices they use;■ w<strong>it</strong>hin these percentages of respondents expressing dissatisfactiononly 2-3 percentage points can be attributed to refusal to grant ormaintain cred<strong>it</strong>;■ in any case not all SMEs actually need to borrow (typically 40% e<strong>it</strong>hersaid they did not or could not recall borrowing in the last three years);■ <strong>and</strong> of those respondents that had sought loans only one sixth hadfailed to get what they asked for.Nevertheless, concern is frequently expressed that there may be anemerging problem to be faced as regards the retreat of larger <strong>banks</strong> fromthe provision of cred<strong>it</strong> to medium-sized enterprises:■■■In Germany in particular there is clear evidence of large <strong>banks</strong> tryingto end their cred<strong>it</strong> relations w<strong>it</strong>h some smaller clients; closingbranches; centralising more of their cred<strong>it</strong> decisions; <strong>and</strong> reducingstaff numbers in some branches. As in the case of <strong>savings</strong> facil<strong>it</strong>ies,these tendencies on the part of mainstream <strong>banks</strong> push ever morepressure on to the <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> cooperative <strong>banks</strong> (DSGV – Survey [2001]).This is often ascribed to the impact of globalisation <strong>and</strong> an increasingfocus on the creation of shareholder value.A related phenomenon is the disruption to SME borrowing patternsthat results from mergers of <strong>banks</strong> w<strong>it</strong>hin countries. Research in thisarea has been conducted for National Bank of Belgium – a countrywhich has seen significant “w<strong>it</strong>hin-market” merger activ<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> whereSMEs are particularly reliant on large <strong>banks</strong> for finance. Degryse,Masschelein <strong>and</strong> M<strong>it</strong>chell [2004] find evidence that firms borrowingfrom acquired <strong>banks</strong> are more likely to lose their lending relationshipthan those already borrowing from the acquiring bank. They also findthat firms borrowing from two of the merging <strong>banks</strong> are less likely tolose their relationship than firms borrowing from only one of them orfrom other <strong>banks</strong> not party to the merger.The move to new cap<strong>it</strong>al adequacy rules for <strong>banks</strong> (Basle II) will raisethe weighting on riskier commercial lending by 50%, which wouldalmost certainly have directly affected the cost of borrowing for SMEs.As a result of this, the impact of the rule change has been softened sothat cap<strong>it</strong>al required for the riskier categories of SME lending will onlyrise by 20%.Therefore, considerable public effort across the EU (see Chapter 4 for moredetail) is being made to improve SME <strong>access</strong> to financing <strong>and</strong> increasethe provision of microcred<strong>it</strong> (here defined as loans under €25,000).In add<strong>it</strong>ion to being an economic measure alone, microfinance can alsobe seen as a way to help counter social exclusion. This is most likelywhere small business entrepreneurs come from minor<strong>it</strong>y groups includingthe unemployed, women or ethnic minor<strong>it</strong>ies.6 The reference here is to a webs<strong>it</strong>e that contains not only the latest reports of the EUObservatory of European SMEs but the capac<strong>it</strong>y to cross-tabulate the supporting ENSRsurvey data.4243


The main reasons for the inadequate level of microfinance provision areusually related to problems of information asymmetries. A major barriercomes from the high risks <strong>and</strong> lack of prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y perceived from theviewpoint of the providers of cred<strong>it</strong>.It is difficult for even a promising business w<strong>it</strong>h no previous track recordto overcome this perception; on average 50% of new businesses inthe EU disappear w<strong>it</strong>hin five years. In add<strong>it</strong>ion, entrepreneurs of smallbusiness often simply <strong>do</strong> not have sufficient collateral to offer to securefinance from trad<strong>it</strong>ional sources w<strong>it</strong>h metho<strong>do</strong>logies geared moretowards larger enterprises.Microfinance also involves high h<strong>and</strong>ling/operational costs as is clear fromthe table below. Spreading these high costs over the life of a three yearloan would add the equivalent of half again to a money-market fundingrate in the sample EU countries <strong>and</strong> about a third to comparable moneymarketfunding rates in the sample Accession countries. This compoundsthe high levels of apparent risk when lenders are dealing w<strong>it</strong>h microenterprisesas costs are incurred up front but revenue accrues through thelife of a loan.Table 2: Loan processing costs for microcred<strong>it</strong>s in eight EuropeaneconomiesUK Deu. Fin. Swe. Eire Est. Pol. Lat.Averageloan size 22000 15000 17000 9000 6000 15000 3000 3000H<strong>and</strong>ling cost:€ per loan 1335 1100 850 700 170 590 275 135% of value 6% 7% 5% 8% 3% 4% 9% 4%Moneymarket rate 3.9% 3.3% 3.3% 2.0% 3.3% 3.9% 9.4% 4.0%Annualisedh<strong>and</strong>ling cost(over 3-yearloan life) 2.1% 2.5% 1.8% 2.8% 1.2% 1.4% 3.2% 1.4%In response to this gap in the market for adequate microfinance, the EU<strong>and</strong> most Member States have been encouraging financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions toprovide more microcred<strong>it</strong>. They have <strong>do</strong>ne this both by offering directfinancial support, <strong>and</strong> also by providing a better enabling environment tosupport SMEs as they develop. The national schemes of Member Statesvary, but tend to share common features. These include the promotion ofthe availabil<strong>it</strong>y of funding to inst<strong>it</strong>utional customers; partial cred<strong>it</strong>provision; partial risk sharing <strong>and</strong> tax incentives. Cred<strong>it</strong> Unions have beenincreasing in numbers, as have NGOs as providers of microcred<strong>it</strong> (forexample the Prince’s Trust in the UK <strong>and</strong> ADIE in France).Microfinance is further made more <strong>access</strong>ible <strong>and</strong> affordable by enablingrisk-sharing in the form of participation in guarantee schemes. A studyfor the European Commission by IDEA Consult [2003] identified mutualguarantee schemes as more prevalent in the south of Europe, particularlyin Italy, France <strong>and</strong> Spain but they have also existed for some time inGermany, Austria, Belgium <strong>and</strong> Luxembourg. By contrast in the Northern<strong>and</strong> Anglo-Saxon countries such as the UK, the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Denmark<strong>and</strong> Finl<strong>and</strong>, public guarantee schemes prevail. In some countries bothpublic <strong>and</strong> private schemes exist (Belgium, France, Austria, Germany <strong>and</strong>Denmark). For seven countries where mutual guarantee schemes areactive (or are beginning to become active) the authors calculate theschemes have an overall reach of 1.5 million enterprises (around 10% ofSMEs in those countries) <strong>and</strong> support new lending of around €10-15bnper year.Source: (EU – Enterprise Policy Group [2004] augmented by authors).4445


Part Three: Issues in the Developing CountriesG. The overall scale of financial systems in developingcountriesThe first thing to note in any discussion of formal financial systems in poorereconomies is that they are <strong>do</strong>minated by commercial <strong>banks</strong>. Figure 1 belowpresents data from the World Bank, World Development Report 7 [2002].It can be seen that bank-based assets in low income countries typicallyamount to around 15% of GDP as compared to around 5% of GDP forstock-market cap<strong>it</strong>alisation <strong>and</strong> only about 2% of GDP for the assets ofnon-bank financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions (NBFIs). In lower-middle income developingcountries, the corresponding percentages of GDP are 24%; 7% <strong>and</strong> 5%respectively. By contrast in some high income countries such as the USA,UK <strong>and</strong> Germany the stock market <strong>and</strong> NBFI totals are 262%, 250% <strong>and</strong>72% of GDP respectively 8 . Country-by-county data to detail this areavailable for almost 100 countries in the database of Beck et al. [2000].Figure 1: Financial system development across countryincome groupsPercentage of GDP60%50%40%30%20%10%0%Central bankassetsDepos<strong>it</strong>money bankassets■ Low income■ Lower-middle incomeOtherfinancialinst<strong>it</strong>utionassetsStock marketcap<strong>it</strong>alization■ Upper-middle income■ High incomePrivate bondmarketcap<strong>it</strong>alizationPublic bondmarketcap<strong>it</strong>alization7 The report is ent<strong>it</strong>led Building Inst<strong>it</strong>utions for Markets8 This is not to say that the relative importance of non-bank finance will not rise asdevelopment proceeds. It is the conclusion from most studies of financial system evolution(e.g. J. Gurley <strong>and</strong> E. Shaw <strong>and</strong> R. Goldsm<strong>it</strong>h) that such a change <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> indeed occur.H. The value of improved individual <strong>access</strong> in developingcountriesThat <strong>access</strong> levels are low in very many developing economies is rarelychallenged, although marked regional differences almost certainly exist.Very l<strong>it</strong>tle systematic work has been <strong>do</strong>ne on the number of peoplehaving <strong>access</strong> to banking services in developing countries <strong>and</strong> forthis reason the next chapter focuses on using proxy financial indicatorsto interpolate between the few points of real data that are available.This lack of data on <strong>access</strong> to banking services probably reflects the strongbias since the early 1980s among international <strong>do</strong>nor organisationstowards microfinance provided via non-bank channels, particularly NGOs.Past discussions of <strong>access</strong> to finance <strong>and</strong> <strong>it</strong>s potential to reduce povertyhave focused disproportionately on the success or otherwise of this activ<strong>it</strong>y.This is now changing, partly because of dissatisfaction w<strong>it</strong>h some of theso-called “apex” organisations that channel <strong>do</strong>nor funding to small NGOsbut also because of the lack of financial self-sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y of many of theprogrammes. There is also a growing recogn<strong>it</strong>ion of the importance offacil<strong>it</strong>ating saving amongst the poor as well as providing cred<strong>it</strong>.Morduch <strong>and</strong> Hayley [2002] provided a comprehensive survey of theissues involved in taking finance to the poor in their paper for CIDA,the Canadian International Development Agency. They concluded thatmicrofinance has proven to be an effective <strong>and</strong> powerful tool for povertyreduction but that like many other development tools <strong>it</strong> has insufficientlypenetrated the poorer strata of society. They go on to suggest that a<strong>savings</strong> first approach will not work as well as a combined cred<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong><strong>savings</strong> approach. At the heart of their analysis is the conclusion thatwhile <strong>savings</strong> may allow households to avoid being pushed into extremepoverty by economic <strong>and</strong> social shocks, only cred<strong>it</strong> creates the add<strong>it</strong>ionaleconomic activ<strong>it</strong>y that can help lift families out of poverty.This view represents the balance of judgement reached by Morduch <strong>and</strong>Hayley but <strong>it</strong> is by no <strong>mean</strong>s uncontroversial. On the one h<strong>and</strong>, there is workthat suggests <strong>access</strong> to microfinance has the potential to significantlyreduce poverty (Kh<strong>and</strong>ker [1998]); on the other h<strong>and</strong> there is researchwhich indicates only a minimal impact on poverty reduction using thesame data (including earlier work by Morduch [1998]). There is also someevidence that there may be a threshold of cumulative loan size beyondwhich microfinance can make a significant dent on poverty (Zaman [1998]).The mixed evidence is partly associated w<strong>it</strong>h the sens<strong>it</strong>iv<strong>it</strong>y of the resultsto metho<strong>do</strong>logical assumptions associated w<strong>it</strong>h the empirical analysis.4647


There is greater consensus <strong>how</strong>ever, on the role of microfinance inreducing vulnerabil<strong>it</strong>y. The provision of microfinance has been found tostrengthen crisis-coping mechanisms, diversify income-earning sources,build assets <strong>and</strong> improve the status of women (Hashemi et al [1996];Montgomery et al [1996]; Morduch [1998]; Zaman [1998]). Considerablework has also been <strong>do</strong>ne by CGAP (World Bank’s Consultative Group toAssist the Poorest), on the importance of <strong>savings</strong> mobilisation to reducingvulnerabil<strong>it</strong>y. A CGAP Donor Brief [2002] identifies saving as superioralternative to cred<strong>it</strong> as a way of surviving shocks <strong>and</strong> a service the poorboth want <strong>and</strong> will pay for. As the poor rarely have <strong>access</strong> to voluntarydepos<strong>it</strong> services offered by formal or semi-formal inst<strong>it</strong>utions they areinstead obliged to save informally: they invest in livestock, hide cash athome, have their <strong>savings</strong> collected by neighbours, or participate in rotating<strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> cred<strong>it</strong> associations. In many cases, these informal <strong>savings</strong> arehigh risk, illiquid, indivisible or impose uniform terms. A cow, for example,can die of disease <strong>and</strong> must be sold as a whole, not in parts, to obtaincash. And the transaction imposes time <strong>and</strong> financial costs.Both the poverty- <strong>and</strong> vulnerabil<strong>it</strong>y-reducing roles of microfinance thusmake <strong>access</strong> to microfinance one of the important potential determinantsfor achieving the improvements in the extreme poverty targets of theMillennium Development Goals (MDGs). Microfinance services targetedto women will also have an indirect effect on other MDGs via improvingwomen’s control over their assets <strong>and</strong> their knowledge of social, health<strong>and</strong> environmental issues. Overall Morduch <strong>and</strong> Hayley s<strong>how</strong> in somedetail evidence that the pos<strong>it</strong>ive impact of microfinance on povertyreduction relates to six out of seven of the Millennium goals.I. Problems w<strong>it</strong>h enterprise <strong>access</strong> in developing countriesOnly a h<strong>and</strong>ful of countries in the world have broad <strong>and</strong> deep financialmarkets involving a significant range of non-bank financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions<strong>and</strong> instruments. For a large major<strong>it</strong>y of developing countries <strong>and</strong> theirenterprises (by number) informal<strong>it</strong>y of financing is the norm. A small sub-setof enterprises in most developing countries face the same sort of choicesas enterprises in developed economies (bank cred<strong>it</strong> versus debt versusequ<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> foreign versus <strong>do</strong>mestic sourcing etc.) but most enterpriseswill not. This point been articulated most forcefully by the Peruvianeconomist de Soto [2000]. He argues that only 25 out of the 200 countriesin the world have reliable <strong>and</strong> legally enforceable property rights <strong>and</strong>ways in which work <strong>and</strong> <strong>savings</strong> can be converted into usable cap<strong>it</strong>al.The reason is the widespread absence of legally enforceable propertyrights in most developing countries. The main result is the pre<strong>do</strong>minanceof informal semi-legal business activ<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> informal <strong>mean</strong>s of financingmost enterprise activ<strong>it</strong>y: for example, there are 2.65 million smallbusinesses in Mexico that are not legally registered. For various reasons,but mainly widespread illegal<strong>it</strong>y, typical patterns of finance are confinedto w<strong>it</strong>hin the household <strong>and</strong> unincorporated business sectors, <strong>and</strong> involvefew if any intersections w<strong>it</strong>h formal financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions.However, when we scrutinise available macroeconomic data this pointgets submerged. Aggregate data on components of the financial sector(e.g. total bank cred<strong>it</strong> or stock market turnover) typically reveal l<strong>it</strong>tle oranything about the number of beneficiaries of finance. This is true, forexample, of the most recent <strong>and</strong> most comprehensive of such data sets,namely that compiled by Beck, Demirguc-Kunt <strong>and</strong> Levine [2000].Enterprise survey data that have been used in the financial structurel<strong>it</strong>erature such as the large IFC survey used by Singh <strong>and</strong> Hamid [1992]typically focus only on a small number of larger enterprises. But subjectto these obvious lim<strong>it</strong>ations of the available data, <strong>it</strong> is possible to makesome general points.First, the fact that banking systems in developing countries, although<strong>do</strong>minant, are also absolutely small leads to serious constraints on theavailabil<strong>it</strong>y of enterprise cred<strong>it</strong>. Typically, that cred<strong>it</strong> (a) goes mainly tolarger companies that are both wholly-legal, involve lower transactioncosts as well as risk <strong>and</strong> may also be well-connected pol<strong>it</strong>ically <strong>and</strong> (b) isvery short-term in nature <strong>and</strong> therefore not of great use for the financingof longer-term investment projects. The evidence presented below givessome support to these propos<strong>it</strong>ions. So both for supply side reasons (theshortage of bank finance) as well as dem<strong>and</strong> side reasons (the imperativesto stay “informal”), a significant proportion of developing countryenterprises by number get excluded from <strong>access</strong> to formal finance.When we enter the lim<strong>it</strong>ed terr<strong>it</strong>ory of larger enterprises, <strong>it</strong> is possible toprovide more specific conclusions. Our knowledge about this is heavilydependent on a large pioneering project carried out by the IFC throughthe 1990s (particularly Singh [1995]). The second phase of the work usedenterprise data from between 50 <strong>and</strong> 100 of the largest enterprises in eachof 10 low <strong>and</strong> middle-income countries (India, Korea, Jordan, Pakistan,Thail<strong>and</strong>, Mexico, Malaysia, Turkey, Zimbabwe <strong>and</strong> Brazil).4849


Some surprising results emerged that ran counter to the a priori expectationsof most economists. Specifically, for these larger enterprises, they found:■ The large corporations relied heavily on external funds■ They relied heavily on new issues of shares to finance their growth ofnet assets■ Developing country (large) enterprises used both external finance <strong>and</strong>particularly equ<strong>it</strong>y finance to a much greater extent than theircounterparts in the advanced economies.Other researchers have qualified these strong results <strong>and</strong> some haveemphasised the small sample biases. For example, Atkin <strong>and</strong> Glen [1992],while agreeing broadly w<strong>it</strong>h Singh’s first point above, found high levelsof variation. In S. Korea, for example the average firm dependency oninternal finance was only 12.8% whereas <strong>it</strong> was as high as 58% in bothPakistan <strong>and</strong> Zimbabwe. In add<strong>it</strong>ion the lim<strong>it</strong>ed number of enterprisesimpacted by these results is confirmed by the small number of stockmarketlistings in most developing countries <strong>and</strong> by the even smallernumber of enterprises whose shares are actively traded. For example thestock markets of Brazil, Egypt, Mexico, Korea <strong>and</strong> Thail<strong>and</strong> are all qu<strong>it</strong>elarge (number of enterprises listed being 470, 1050, 185, 720, <strong>and</strong> 390respectively). However, in all these cases somewhere between 40% <strong>and</strong>75% of all turnover is accounted for by just 5% of the listed enterprises(23, 52, 9, 36 <strong>and</strong> 19 enterprises).The IFC results are also consistent w<strong>it</strong>h the propos<strong>it</strong>ion that internationalportfolio flows of finance, including those from Development FinanceInst<strong>it</strong>utions (DFIs) <strong>and</strong> through foreign <strong>banks</strong>, are heavily concentrated onlarger enterprises in each country but <strong>do</strong> l<strong>it</strong>tle or nothing to relieve thefinancing problems of the mass of enterprises. This is also clear from thetwo part table overleaf reproduced in simplified form from a major draftstudy based on what is now possibly the best source for work onenterprise <strong>access</strong>. This is the World Business Environment Survey (WBES)©2000 The World Bank Group under which a sample of 10,000 firms in100 countries throughout the world were asked to rate the extent towhich specific factors in the business environment were problematic fortheir operation <strong>and</strong> growth 9 .The first part of the table s<strong>how</strong>s that investment funds, developmentfinance schemes <strong>and</strong> state-directed lending schemes are essentially onlyrelevant for medium <strong>and</strong> large scale firms that already have significant<strong>access</strong> to bank finance. The major subst<strong>it</strong>ute for bank finance amongst smallfirms is less formal sources of finance particularly family <strong>and</strong> friends but alsomoney lenders (which may well include cred<strong>it</strong> unions <strong>and</strong> co-operatives).Table 3: Enterprise financing patterns by size of firm <strong>and</strong> region% of total financing from: Small firms Medium-sized Larger firmsInv. Funds / Dev. Finance / State 2.0 7.9 7.1Banks & Leasing Companies 12.9 20.2 26.5Supplier Cred<strong>it</strong> 5.3 7.5 6.2Informal sources* 14.1 4.5 2.1Internal Funds / Retained Earnings 50.8 50.9 42.8Equ<strong>it</strong>y 4.4 4.9 4.7Unspecified 10.5 4.1 10.6% of total E. Asia S. Asia E. Asia Latin CIS C & E OECDfinancing from: Devel. Tigers Amer. EuropeInv. Funds /Dev. Finance / State 1.6 5.2 3.2 3.1 6.3 8.7 4.3Banks & LeasingCompanies 21.2 22.4 17.0 25.1 17.1 8.0 19.4Supplier Cred<strong>it</strong> 3.2 2.5 7.9 10.2 4.6 5.8 4.8Informal sources* 11.6 7.4 6.2 5.4 11.1 8.9 4.6Internal Funds /Retained Earnings 33.9 26.5 48.3 43.2 53.9 70.5 39.1Equ<strong>it</strong>y 2.7 6.4 5.8 3.2 8.6 1.4 8.5Unspecified 25.8 29.6 11.6 9.8 -1.6 -3.3 19.3*Family, Friends, Money-lenders, etc9 The sample was not a simple r<strong>and</strong>om one <strong>and</strong> thus characteristics of the sampled firmsw<strong>it</strong>hin a country cannot be taken as indicative of all firms but may be “biased” towardscertain types.5051


A more confusing pattern of migration from less formal to more formalsources of finance is apparent when looking at the same data on aregional basis as s<strong>how</strong>n in the second part of the table. Desp<strong>it</strong>e regionalvariations (which may be coming from different sample mixes of firmsby size) this <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> suggest that bank <strong>and</strong> similar finance is less relevantto more rapidly advancing economies (the East Asian Tigers, China, thestronger CIS <strong>and</strong> Central <strong>and</strong> Eastern European economies). State directedschemes can be more significant here but reliance on less formal sourcesis still relatively high <strong>and</strong> retained earnings <strong>and</strong> embedded equ<strong>it</strong>y evenmore significant.Other qual<strong>it</strong>ative evidence from the same survey based on entrepreneur/manager perceptions of the constraints to development reinforce thispicture, w<strong>it</strong>h the constraint coming from lack of finance ranking ashigh if not higher than many other constraints such as tax, corruption,infrastructure, etc.These various points together suggest that the financing s<strong>it</strong>uation forenterprises in developing countries can be characterised by:■■■A chronic general failure of formal financial systems to help mostenterprises because of widespread informal<strong>it</strong>y of business associatedw<strong>it</strong>h weak legally-enforceable property rightsA heavy general dependence on commercial bank financing of thosebusinesses that have <strong>access</strong> to formal financeA dualistic structure in which a sub-set of the larger enterprises ofsome developing economies make a surprisingly high use of external<strong>and</strong> especially equ<strong>it</strong>y financing, including international portfolio flows(where cap<strong>it</strong>al accounts are liberalised).J. Supply constraints on <strong>access</strong> to banking<strong>and</strong> microfinanceSystematic l<strong>it</strong>erature on what constrains the availabil<strong>it</strong>y of finance indeveloping countries is rather fragmented <strong>and</strong> not linked to the debateabout exclusion in developed economies.Four factors are, <strong>how</strong>ever, commonly mentioned:■ the sparse coverage of rural areas by bank branch networks;■ an unwillingness by commercial <strong>banks</strong> to focus on rural <strong>and</strong> SMEbusiness;■ the very high cost of formal banking services;■ <strong>and</strong> the lack of financial self sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y for most microfinanceinst<strong>it</strong>utions.Work by the authors of this paper has started to address the third of theseissues in a systematic way. This indicates that the cost of intermediation<strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> have a significant bearing on the volume of banking servicessupplied to an economy (see box below). This f<strong>it</strong>s w<strong>it</strong>h the underlyingtheory described in section B – if the transactions costs of exchanginggoods <strong>and</strong> services in a monetised form via a formal banking system arehigh relative even to the cost inefficiencies of barter, then the rural poorwill not only not find <strong>it</strong> economically worthwhile using <strong>banks</strong> but theymay not even find <strong>it</strong> worth using money for much of their economicactiv<strong>it</strong>y.The acute nature of this problem in a developing country context isevidenced by experience in Kenya, a country which, as has already beenmentioned, has a relatively developed banking sector that mobilisessignificant volumes of finance relative to GDP. Estimates by the KenyaBankers Association suggest that the minimum costs of setting up a ruralbank branch are above $250,000. The volume of small-ticket transactionsneeded to cover such costs is way above likely business volumes in poorrural areas. Even in an urban context, calculations by Peachey [2004]suggest that a basic salary account for a professional (teacher, <strong>do</strong>ctor, civilservant, etc) would cost at least €10 per month to run <strong>and</strong> require a monthlyincome of around €8,000 for the interest on the average monthlybalance on such an account to cover the charges made for using <strong>it</strong>.5253


Box 3: Banking costs <strong>and</strong> the scale of banking activ<strong>it</strong>yFigure 3: Operating income as % earning assetsThe diagram below s<strong>how</strong>s (left h<strong>and</strong> side <strong>and</strong> top segment) theoperating costs (as percentages of income-earning assets) of different<strong>banks</strong> in a sample of European trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies. These costs arebenchmarked against good practice in EU <strong>banks</strong> (s<strong>how</strong>n by thehorizontal <strong>do</strong>tted line). Better <strong>banks</strong> (black circles) are distinguishedfrom weaker <strong>banks</strong> in order to see <strong>how</strong> far each category of bank ineach country diverges in terms of their costs from the EU benchmark.Banking sector depth is s<strong>how</strong>n in the bars in the bottom segment ofthe diagram. It is clearly seen that the banking systems w<strong>it</strong>h greaterdepth (<strong>and</strong> almost certainly serving more customers) are those wherethe gaps in cost performance by <strong>banks</strong> vis-à-vis the EU st<strong>and</strong>ard arelower <strong>and</strong> where the bulk of the banking system <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> not lag too farbehind the performance of the best <strong>banks</strong> in the system.30%25%20%15%10%5%0%CroatiaHungaryPol<strong>and</strong>EstoniaBulgariaLatviaL<strong>it</strong>huaniaRussiaSerbiaUkraineKazakhstanArmeniaFigure 2: Operating costs as % earning assets30%25%41% 37% 36% 32% 25%20% 20%18%14%13%7%20%15%67%10%5%0%CroatiaHungaryPol<strong>and</strong>EstoniaBulgariaLatvia41% 37% 36% 32% 25%L<strong>it</strong>huaniaRussia20% 20%SerbiaUkraineKazakhstanArmenia18%14%13%7%Chart Key:Circles indicate aggregate performance of different group <strong>banks</strong>in each country:- center of circle s<strong>how</strong>s level of performance (read againstside axes)- size of circle s<strong>how</strong>s market share of group of <strong>banks</strong>- dark blue circles s<strong>how</strong> performance of best quarter of <strong>banks</strong>in each country- light blue circles s<strong>how</strong> performance of rest of banking system- <strong>do</strong>tted lines indicate average performance of lendingEU <strong>banks</strong>.67%5455


As already noted, microfinance has been the main instrument of choiceof aid <strong>do</strong>nors <strong>and</strong> some governments in the attack on financial exclusionin low income countries in the past 10-15 years.Figure 4: MFI penetration (% of population)Source: Based on Daley-Harris (2003).Microfinance Inst<strong>it</strong>utions (MFIs) have been widely perceived to be a route toextend cred<strong>it</strong> to sections of society that are denied <strong>access</strong> to mainstreamcommercial <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> other more trad<strong>it</strong>ional financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions.However, Honahan [2004], identifies the very lim<strong>it</strong>ed penetration specialistmicrocred<strong>it</strong> actually achieves even in the poorest countries. Figure 4,taken from Honahan’s paper, s<strong>how</strong>s <strong>how</strong> small a proportion of thepopulation that microfinance typically addresses. He also s<strong>how</strong>s <strong>how</strong> l<strong>it</strong>tle<strong>it</strong> typically adds to <strong>do</strong>mestic cred<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong> goes on to say:56Distribution of countries by microfinance penetration40%35%30%25%20%15%10%5%0%0-1%1-2% 2-4% 4-6% 6-8% 8-10% 10-12% 12%+Clients as % population“a plausible interpretation of the [reasons that prevent microfinancefrom exp<strong>and</strong>ing to full potential] is that effective microfinance provisionfor low income households <strong>and</strong> low-value added microenterprises isintensive in resources that are not plentiful in developing countries.Most likely these resources involve strategic management.Only when management resources are applied on a sufficiently largescale (whether by commercial bankers, NGO activists, or public servants)will microfinance provision break through the threshold <strong>and</strong> becomefirmly established on the scale that has been achieved, for example,in Bangladesh.“Honanhan then makes the point that even where microfinance can offera good return on cap<strong>it</strong>al, <strong>it</strong> rarely <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> so if proper account is taken ofthe managerial time <strong>and</strong> effort required to get a prof<strong>it</strong>able operationworking. This helps explain why most of what is now microfinance has overthe last two centuries come from the char<strong>it</strong>able sector.Separately, a survey by the Asian Development Bank (Fern<strong>and</strong>o [2002]<strong>and</strong> [2003]) together w<strong>it</strong>h other relevant papers such as Yaron <strong>and</strong>M<strong>it</strong>hika [2004] identify the following constraints on the expansion ofmicrofinance inst<strong>it</strong>utions as being among the most important:■■Complementar<strong>it</strong>ies w<strong>it</strong>h commercial <strong>banks</strong>. MFI activ<strong>it</strong>ies are oftenconstrained by the qual<strong>it</strong>y of the commercial banking systems in thecountries where they operate. If banking systems are weak as, forexample, in Central Asian trans<strong>it</strong>ional economies, non-bank MFIs haveproblems in finding a reliable place to park the depos<strong>it</strong>s they raise <strong>and</strong>also experience delays <strong>and</strong> high transaction costs in w<strong>it</strong>hdrawingdepos<strong>it</strong>s. Some MFIs in Asia have lost significant depos<strong>it</strong>s because ofbank failures. Similarly, when “bad” <strong>banks</strong> are the norm, MFIs facel<strong>it</strong>tle or no compet<strong>it</strong>ion in the main product areas. A strong <strong>and</strong>compet<strong>it</strong>ive mainstream banking system is complementary to effectiveMFI activ<strong>it</strong>y. This is partly because <strong>it</strong> directly helps to lower the transactioncosts of the MFIs, but also because of the direct involvement ofcommercial <strong>banks</strong> in MFI-type activ<strong>it</strong>ies (e.g. via specialised subsidiaries)that is propelled by compet<strong>it</strong>ion in banking. Developments in Kenyanbanking in the past three years provide a good example (WSBI [2004]).Legal<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> Governance. The NGO-MFI format is seriously lim<strong>it</strong>ed interms of the amount of ongoing expansion (<strong>and</strong> so <strong>access</strong>) that <strong>it</strong> cansafely achieve. Even in very large <strong>and</strong> experienced MFI systems such asthat in Bangladesh, these problems persist. The legal status of MFIs isoften such as to preclude expansion into certain types of financialservices <strong>and</strong> especially depos<strong>it</strong>-taking. The real ownership <strong>and</strong> controlof the MFIs is less than clear <strong>and</strong> so too is their accountabil<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong>governance. Where co-operative organisations are heavily involved inthe provision of financial services (as, for example, in Sri Lanka, thePhilippines <strong>and</strong> Kenya), regulatory arrangements often represent apoor compromise between the needs of cooperatives generally <strong>and</strong>their financial functions.57


■The result, to somewhat over-simplify a complex picture, is that manyMFIs cannot legally mobilise the funds to support ongoing expansion.But where they <strong>do</strong> so, they often proceed w<strong>it</strong>hout adequate regulationof their use of funds <strong>and</strong> so expose savers to considerable risks.The terms on which MFI services are offered. It has been a commonassumption amongst some advocates of microcred<strong>it</strong> that <strong>it</strong>s mission toserve the poor <strong>mean</strong>s that the cred<strong>it</strong> must be provided at low interestrates. This view is increasingly discred<strong>it</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> for a very obviousreason. Low cost cred<strong>it</strong> must imply e<strong>it</strong>her (a) that the MFI providingthe cred<strong>it</strong> can operate w<strong>it</strong>h low costs <strong>and</strong>/or (b) that <strong>it</strong>s services aresubsidised e<strong>it</strong>her by the state or by <strong>do</strong>nors. In low-income countriessustained fiscal subsidies are not available because of the very lim<strong>it</strong>edfiscal capac<strong>it</strong>y of governments. Where governments have sought toresource MFI inst<strong>it</strong>utions the costs have often been huge relative to thebenef<strong>it</strong>s generated 10 . Donor subsidies will typically be available onlyfor short periods of time. Similarly, <strong>and</strong> for reasons to <strong>do</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h hightransactions costs <strong>and</strong> risks, most MFIs <strong>do</strong> not have particularly lowoperating costs when compared, for example, w<strong>it</strong>h local <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong>certainly w<strong>it</strong>h good st<strong>and</strong>ard international <strong>banks</strong>.Morduch <strong>and</strong> Hayley [2002] also address the issue of financial sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y<strong>and</strong> challenge the received wis<strong>do</strong>m of the mid-1990s when an influentialstudy of twelve microfinance inst<strong>it</strong>utions across Asia, Africa <strong>and</strong> LatinAmerica by Hulme <strong>and</strong> Mosely [1996] had indicated a distinct trade-offbetween outreach to the poorest <strong>and</strong> inst<strong>it</strong>utional financial sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y.Five years later Morduch <strong>and</strong> Hayley conclude:“Microfinance compares favourably to other interventions particularlyw<strong>it</strong>h regard to cost effectiveness <strong>and</strong> prospects for sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y:■Cost-effectiveness: An advantage of microfinance is that <strong>do</strong>nor investmentis recycled <strong>and</strong> reused [Wright 2000]. Direct comparisons <strong>do</strong>ne byKh<strong>and</strong>ker [1998] s<strong>how</strong> that microfinance can be a more cost-effectivedevelopmental tool than alternatives including formal rural financialintermediation, targeted food interventions, <strong>and</strong> rural infrastructuredevelopment projects. More over, unlike many other interventions,costs for microfinance tend to diminish w<strong>it</strong>h the scale of outreach(Rhyne [1997]; Christen et al [1996])10 For example a recent review of government-owned financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions in Kenya includingsome focused on agricultural cred<strong>it</strong> has found (a) that the government has directly orindirectly funded 82 % of the net resources used for the lending <strong>and</strong> (b) that only 850performing borrowers appear in the current balance-sheets w<strong>it</strong>h an implied fiscal cost ofeach performing loan of some Ksh 27 million – around $350,000 (far more than the facevalue of most loans). See Murgatroyd [2004].58■Sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y: Few, if any, other development tools have the potentialto become sustainable such that, after in<strong>it</strong>ial start-up grants, newinputs are not required for every future client.- There need not be a trade-off between reaching the poorest <strong>and</strong>attaining financial sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y. Although there are no rigorouseconometric models to substantiate <strong>it</strong>, there is ample evidence thatMFIs targeting the poorest can fare as well financially as those that<strong>do</strong>n’t (Gibbons <strong>and</strong> Meehan [2000]; Churchill [2000])- There is also ample anec<strong>do</strong>tal evidence that MFIs that target poorerclients can achieve substantially higher repayment rates than thosethat target richer clients- It should be noted that emphasizing financial sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y aboveall else can have the practical effect of excluding the poorestbecause of the widespread misperception that the poorest are agreater cred<strong>it</strong> risk <strong>and</strong> the real<strong>it</strong>y that the un<strong>it</strong> costs of small loanstend to exceed the un<strong>it</strong> costs of larger loans.”However, the defin<strong>it</strong>ion of self-sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y used by Morduch & Hayleyis implic<strong>it</strong>ly lim<strong>it</strong>ed to an MFI being able to plough back repaymentsfrom earlier cred<strong>it</strong>s w<strong>it</strong>hout <strong>it</strong>s funding base being gradually absorbedby operating costs once <strong>do</strong>nor support is w<strong>it</strong>hdrawn. It says nothingabout the capac<strong>it</strong>y of MFIs to break out of the <strong>do</strong>nor constraint.Other commentators, notably through the CGAP forum, are focusingincreasingly on <strong>how</strong> <strong>savings</strong> can be mobilised from the poor to providefunding for pro-poor cred<strong>it</strong> once <strong>do</strong>nor sources decline.The CGAP [2002] <strong>do</strong>nor brief identifies four required features of a“pro-poor” <strong>savings</strong> product:■ Secur<strong>it</strong>y: Secure <strong>savings</strong> are not in jeopardy from fraud, theft, fire, <strong>and</strong>relatives’ dem<strong>and</strong>s. Safety is paramount, even in the face of inflation.■ Low transaction costs: Proxim<strong>it</strong>y is essential to reduce the hightransaction costs of making depos<strong>it</strong>s <strong>and</strong> w<strong>it</strong>hdrawals. Convenientopening times <strong>and</strong> minimal paperwork are also important.■ Appropriate design: Individual voluntary depos<strong>it</strong> products that allowfrequent depos<strong>it</strong>s of small, variable amounts <strong>and</strong> quick <strong>access</strong> to fundsare best. Contractual <strong>savings</strong> are also useful for planned future lifecycleexpend<strong>it</strong>ures such as weddings, funerals, <strong>and</strong> birth celebrations.■ Interest rates: If transaction costs are low, rural <strong>savings</strong> takes placeeven w<strong>it</strong>h negative real returns – indicating that the poor can be relativelyinsens<strong>it</strong>ive to interest rates as a prior<strong>it</strong>y when evaluating <strong>savings</strong>options. Nevertheless, dem<strong>and</strong> for <strong>savings</strong> products <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> increase asreal interest rates rise.”59


An earlier CGAP Focus Paper [1998] suggests that to deliver these features,an inst<strong>it</strong>ution providing depos<strong>it</strong> services for the poor needs the capac<strong>it</strong>yfor ‘safe <strong>and</strong> sound’ depos<strong>it</strong> operations. This requires strong managementof cred<strong>it</strong>, liquid<strong>it</strong>y, <strong>and</strong> interest rate risk as well as internal controls,management information systems, the financial capac<strong>it</strong>y to w<strong>it</strong>hst<strong>and</strong>external shocks (e.g., inflation <strong>and</strong> devaluation) <strong>and</strong> adequate cap<strong>it</strong>al.The paper acknowledges that inst<strong>it</strong>utions collecting depos<strong>it</strong>s from thepublic should be properly supervised, but suggests that not all require thesame type of formal central bank supervision <strong>and</strong> that a combination ofstrategies should be used to tailor accountabil<strong>it</strong>y requirements to thescale of the depos<strong>it</strong> inst<strong>it</strong>ution. Finally, the obvious but often forgottenpoint is made that for inst<strong>it</strong>utions to mobilise <strong>savings</strong> from the poor theymust be comm<strong>it</strong>ted to exp<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>access</strong> to greater numbers of the poor.CGAP conclude that <strong>banks</strong> are more likely to be able to satisfy suchrequirements than less formal NGO <strong>and</strong> self-help based MFIs althoughthey <strong>do</strong> suggest specialist microfinance <strong>and</strong>/or cooperative <strong>banks</strong> might<strong>do</strong> better than mainstream <strong>banks</strong>.K. Other issues affecting <strong>access</strong> in developing countries1. The electronic revolution <strong>and</strong> <strong>access</strong>Financial sector development has in the past been “inst<strong>it</strong>ution oriented”.As we saw above, commercial <strong>banks</strong> provide the main basis forfinancing in many developing countries w<strong>it</strong>h parallel NBFIs such asmicrofinance inst<strong>it</strong>utions emerging to challenge them in some aspectsof financial delivery. But in advanced countries this approach isincreasingly being replaced by a “functional approach”. This newapproach unbundles financial services into various functions/commod<strong>it</strong>ies w<strong>it</strong>h their own production <strong>and</strong> delivery structures thatare not necessarily linked physically to particular <strong>banks</strong> or NBFIs.This in turn changes the requirements of effective regulation.The significance of the rapid technological changes in communication<strong>and</strong> especially the internet is that <strong>it</strong> makes some aspects of thisfunctional approach relevant also in developing countries. Above allthis new approach <strong>mean</strong>s that financial systems no longer need sucha strong base-infrastructure of commercial <strong>banks</strong>. Nor <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> a nationalbase of delivery seem so important. Africa Online, for example is agrowing internet provider in several parts of Africa outside <strong>it</strong>s SouthAfrican base.Box 4: Mobile phones in the developing worldIn 1990 there were just 11 million mobile phone numbers worldwide.By 1998 the number had jumped to 320 million <strong>and</strong> currentestimates are of more than 500 million users.Some developing countries typify the possibil<strong>it</strong>ies of leapfroggingusing mobile phones. Zimbabwe saw wireless subscribers rocketto 174,000 in 1999- growth of more than 800 percent, thefastest in the world. In Botswana, Cote d’Ivoire <strong>and</strong> Rw<strong>and</strong>a,wireless phone subscribers outnumber fixed-line users. Brazil hasmore than 150 million mobile phone subscribers, more than allthe Nordic countries combined. W<strong>it</strong>h a devastated fixed networkafter more than 20 years of civil war, a<strong>do</strong>pting cellular technologywas the obvious choice for Cambodia, <strong>and</strong> w<strong>it</strong>hin a year mobilesubscribers outnumbered fixed telephones. Even though <strong>it</strong>s percap<strong>it</strong>a income is among the worlds lowest, Cambodia nowsurpasses 31 countries in overall telephone penetration –including countries w<strong>it</strong>h much higher incomes.Source: Claessens, Stijn, Glaessner Thomas <strong>and</strong> Klingebiel Daniela,E-Finance in Emerging Markets: Is Leapfrogging Possible? Financial SectorDiscussion Paper No. 7, World Bank, June 2001E-finance has been growing rapidly in many markets (see the box aboveextracted from the paper by Claessens et al. [2001]). The rate <strong>and</strong>degree of penetration seems to depend on a variety of factors amongstwhich the size <strong>and</strong> qual<strong>it</strong>y of a country’s telecommunications infrastructureis among the most important. But this no longer needs toawa<strong>it</strong> the development of hard-wired l<strong>and</strong>-lines. In many emerging<strong>and</strong> lower income countries, mobile telephony is perm<strong>it</strong>ting thedegree of connectiv<strong>it</strong>y to exp<strong>and</strong> far more rapidly than would everhave been thought possible.Telephone communication of a good st<strong>and</strong>ard is clearly a necessarycond<strong>it</strong>ion for e-finance to take off, but this no longer needs to awa<strong>it</strong>a country’s “development” <strong>and</strong> large-scale investment in publicinfrastructure. Clearly incomes <strong>and</strong> several other factors also helpdetermine the point at which the penetration rates of e-finance mightbecome significant in any particular country.6061


However, based on a simple preliminary model, Claessens <strong>and</strong> hiscolleagues have estimated a progression of penetration rates for asample of industrial, emerging <strong>and</strong> low income economies through2010 (see Table 4 below).Table 4: E-Finance penetration; projected through 2010 (percent)Germany 7 56 92Thail<strong>and</strong> 3 19 68South Africa 3 19 68Mexico 3 19 68India 3 19 68Portugal 3 23 73China 3 19 68Brazil 3 19 68Irel<strong>and</strong> 10 62 93Norway 22 78 97Argentina 3 19 68Although projections of this type are inev<strong>it</strong>ably speculative, thepossibil<strong>it</strong>ies indicated by the table are impressive. They suggest that ina period as short as ten years, many of the richer industrial countriescould be seeing e-finance penetration rates above 80 percent w<strong>it</strong>h manyof today’s low-income countries not too far behind. Emerging marketeconomies already boast the world’s third largest internet bank.Bradesco bank in Brazil has 1.7 million clients online <strong>and</strong> provides <strong>it</strong>smore than 700,000 corporate clients an electronic s<strong>it</strong>e w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>access</strong> toinsurance, brokerage <strong>and</strong> pension fund services. Transaction paymentsservices for consumers have been placed on smart cards that consumerscan <strong>do</strong>wnload from their computers.Will mass <strong>access</strong> to banking services be improved by this revolution?The answer is almost certainly yes w<strong>it</strong>h the 10-15% of poor-countrypopulations presently being served by conventional banking beingincreased significantly in at least some poorer countries during thenext 10-20 years. This will not <strong>mean</strong> <strong>how</strong>ever that universal <strong>access</strong> willbecome the norm. The lowering of banking costs made possible bythe new technologies seems certain to exclude the more disadvantagedin most poor societies in much the same way that bank closures<strong>and</strong> more cost-conscious <strong>banks</strong> have <strong>do</strong>ne in, for example, Br<strong>it</strong>ain<strong>and</strong> France.Personal computer use to some extent shifts banking cost from thebank to the individual <strong>and</strong> this fact alone will continue to excludemany of the poorest individuals <strong>and</strong> families. Similarly the legal barriersare not trivial – in some countries the formal legal requirement foropening a bank account are formidable (e.g. the registration ofsignature by a notary).2. The impact of HIV/AIDSThe economic impact of HIV/AIDS across developing economies is well<strong>do</strong>cumented. The impact on the poor is particularly acute – householdsw<strong>it</strong>h only lim<strong>it</strong>ed sources of income can rapidly enter a vicious spiral ofdecline as income collapses, expenses rise <strong>and</strong> <strong>savings</strong> run out. The endpoint is often to cut into living expend<strong>it</strong>ures in ways that not onlyfurther weaken the health of the person(s) suffering the disease but alsoundermine the future earning capac<strong>it</strong>y of survivors. Specific problemsarise in <strong>access</strong>ing family bank accounts in households where e<strong>it</strong>herminors or the ill<strong>it</strong>erate old have to take over as head of household. In a<strong>do</strong>nor brief CGAP [2003] strongly recommends against microfinanceprogrammes solely targeted at commun<strong>it</strong>ies w<strong>it</strong>h a high incidence ofHIV/AIDS because of the very high cost overheads <strong>and</strong> risks to financialself-sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y. The brief <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong>, <strong>how</strong>ever, suggest that diversifiedprogrammes can achieve self-sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y, while still helpingcommun<strong>it</strong>ies build resilience to the financial impact of the disease. It mapsout the following matrix of target clients <strong>and</strong> required products:Figure 5: CGAP Matrix for addressing regions affectedby HIV/AIDSWho can use financialservices in regions affectedby HIV/AIDS?HIV+ individuals butstill productiveother productive familymemberssurviving spouses, children,or parentshouseholds unaffectedby HIV/AIDS<strong>What</strong> products <strong>and</strong> policiesare responsive to theirneeds?flexible <strong>savings</strong>education trusts for minorsemergency loansburial insuranceloan insurance (in caseof death)acceptance of younger/older clients6263


3. Rem<strong>it</strong>tances <strong>and</strong> the fight against organised cri<strong>mean</strong>d terrorismGlobal official figures estimate that 200 million migrants support morethan half a billion people every year through rem<strong>it</strong>tances worthUS$232 billion. This figure might increase 50% if transfers throughnon-official channels are included. For the migrants sending thismoney, rem<strong>it</strong>tances also often represent their first exposure to bankingservices in their host country. The agents that undertake this businesshave trad<strong>it</strong>ionally faced three major challenges to building the flow offunds through formal channels: (a) to reduce the cost of transfers(which can be as high as 20-25% of the amount transferred), (b) tosecure end-to-end delivery <strong>and</strong> (c) to enhance secur<strong>it</strong>y. They now faceother challenges that threaten to raise barriers to <strong>access</strong> for the poorestcustomers in particular. These are the “know-your-customer” <strong>and</strong>identification requirements built into anti money-laundering (AML)regulations <strong>and</strong> more recently into rules aimed at disrupting the flowof funds to <strong>and</strong> between terrorist organisations. Many migrant workersare not l<strong>it</strong>erate. For some of them (for example workers in SouthAfrican mines) their employment will give status <strong>and</strong> <strong>access</strong> to bankaccounts <strong>and</strong> rem<strong>it</strong>tance mechanisms. For many others, <strong>how</strong>ever,operating as casual workers <strong>and</strong> in the personal services industry,this option is not available. Indeed their personal <strong>do</strong>cumentation,employment <strong>and</strong> residence status may be at best borderline legal <strong>and</strong>certainly not enough to satisfy the AML/anti-terrorism requirements ofmainstream <strong>banks</strong> operating rem<strong>it</strong>tances business. A major Spanish<strong>savings</strong> bank in<strong>it</strong>iative in the area is discussed in Chapter 5.3. DIMENSIONS OF ACCESSIN DIFFERENT REGIONSA. OverviewOne of the objectives set for this study was to identify the different levelsof <strong>access</strong> to banking services for both households <strong>and</strong> small <strong>and</strong> mediumsizedenterprises. Some direct estimates for <strong>access</strong> in these senses havebeen found in the l<strong>it</strong>erature for the advanced economies of the Euro Area,Br<strong>it</strong>ain <strong>and</strong> North America but unfortunately very l<strong>it</strong>tle firm evidenceexists for developing countries. <strong>What</strong> l<strong>it</strong>tle direct data there are fordeveloping countries, tends to focus on the lim<strong>it</strong>s there are to <strong>access</strong> tomicrofinance <strong>and</strong> refer much less to lim<strong>it</strong>s to <strong>access</strong> to general bankingservices. At the heart of this problem are three weaknesses in the waybanking data are prepared:■■■data on numbers of people <strong>access</strong>ing personal financial services areoften not even known w<strong>it</strong>hin <strong>banks</strong> – they often have to rely onexpensive market research to tell the difference between the numberof customers <strong>and</strong> the number of accounts;regulators (until very recently) have not been interested in retailtransaction volumes, concentrating instead on data relating tostabil<strong>it</strong>y. Thus the multilateral agency databases that collate bankingsector data rarely capture this account usage in a coherent way;identification of SME activ<strong>it</strong>y is very poor <strong>and</strong> even worse for microenterprises– where <strong>it</strong> is identified, defin<strong>it</strong>ions are often inconsistentbetween countries.The issue of measuring <strong>access</strong> to finance for SMEs outside the advancedindustrial economies is not tractable except by reference to the largeWorld Business Environment Survey completed for World Bank <strong>and</strong> referredto in Section 9 of Chapter 2. No further work has been <strong>do</strong>ne on this.6465


Figure 6: Proportion of South African populationusing key banking servicesCred<strong>it</strong>57%TransactionsSavingsThe gold st<strong>and</strong>ard for identifying problems w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>access</strong> for households wouldbe the sort of comparisons of banked versus un-banked populationsdescribed for the US <strong>and</strong> Mexico C<strong>it</strong>y in the Caskey, Ruíz Durán <strong>and</strong> Solo[2004] study. A second-best would be to know, at least, what proportionof the adult population have <strong>access</strong> to (a) bank payment services, (b)bank accounts (c) <strong>savings</strong> products <strong>and</strong> (d) cred<strong>it</strong>. Perhaps the clearestexample of this is the chart reproduced here in a slightly reduced formfrom the FinMark Trust (South Africa) webs<strong>it</strong>e 11 .This, <strong>how</strong>ever, represents the lim<strong>it</strong> of what <strong>it</strong> has been possible to find ona consistent basis <strong>do</strong>wn to product level for developing countries. Stone[2005] in his stocktake on indicators of <strong>access</strong> for UK Department forInternational Development identifies only ten countries for which surveydata is consistently available on this indicator.48%11 www.finmark.org.za – The FinMark Trust was established in March 2002 w<strong>it</strong>h in<strong>it</strong>ialfunding of GBP 5 million from the UK Government’s Department for International Development.Its mission is “Making Financial Markets Work for the Poor” <strong>and</strong> in pursu<strong>it</strong> of this objective<strong>it</strong> supports inst<strong>it</strong>utional <strong>and</strong> organisational development that will increase <strong>access</strong> toservices by the un- <strong>and</strong> under-banked of South Africa, Botswana, Lesotho, Swazil<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong>Namibia.49%Putting all the sources together the following spectrum of <strong>access</strong> emerges:Table 5: Proportion of surveyed (adult) populationw<strong>it</strong>h bank/<strong>savings</strong> accountsEU15 average 90% Swazil<strong>and</strong> 35%Un<strong>it</strong>ed States 91% Namibia 28%South Africa 49% Djibouti 12 25%Botswana 47% Mexico C<strong>it</strong>y 21%Brazil (urban) 43% Lesotho 17%Colombia (Bogota) 39% Tanzania 6%In add<strong>it</strong>ion to this there are a number of countries for which <strong>it</strong> is possibleto piece together the number of accounts at different types of bank <strong>and</strong>near-bank financial inst<strong>it</strong>ution <strong>and</strong> compare these to the adult populationof each country. Table 6 s<strong>how</strong>s selected examples.Table 6: Commercial <strong>and</strong> <strong>savings</strong> bank accounts per hea<strong>do</strong>f adult populationCôte d’Ivoire10 million adults- CECP, the postal<strong>savings</strong> bank,services 875,000accounts through194 outlets <strong>and</strong>has a depos<strong>it</strong>market share of4% but <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> nolending- the rest of the<strong>banks</strong> service just660,000 accountsthrough 150 outlets- overall, there isroughly one bankor <strong>savings</strong> bankaccount per sixadults.Kenya17 million adults- KPOSB, also apostbank, services1.9 mn accountsthrough over470 outlets <strong>and</strong>has a market shareof under 3% <strong>and</strong>also <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> nolending- the rest of the<strong>banks</strong> service justover 2 mn accountsthrough 583 outlets- overall, there isroughly one bankor <strong>savings</strong> bankaccount per fouradults.Chile10 million adults- Banco Esta<strong>do</strong>,services 11 millionaccounts throughover 378 outlets,has a depos<strong>it</strong>market share of17% <strong>and</strong> a 15%loan market share- the rest of the<strong>banks</strong> service just1.1 mn accountsvia 1500 outlets- overall, there isjust over one bankor <strong>savings</strong> bankfor every adult.Spain31 million adults- Spanish <strong>savings</strong><strong>banks</strong> service52 million accountsthrough morethan 20,000outlets, has amarket share ofjust under 50% fordepos<strong>it</strong>s <strong>and</strong> loans- the rest of the<strong>banks</strong> service34 million accountsvia 19,000 outlets- overall, there areroughly 2 bank or<strong>savings</strong> accountsfor every adult.12 The data for Djibouti differentiates by location w<strong>it</strong>h 27% of respondents in Djibouti C<strong>it</strong>yhaving an account compared to 19% in other urban areas <strong>and</strong> barely 6% in rural areas.6667


B. Metho<strong>do</strong>logy for overcoming the lack of solid dataon <strong>access</strong>Given the lack of specific country data on <strong>access</strong> to finance, the only optionis to identify a set of proxy or “tracking” variables that are consistentlyavailable for a broad spectrum of countries, <strong>and</strong> that might point to levelsof <strong>access</strong>, albe<strong>it</strong> indirectly. Two options are used in this paper.The first involves looking at data for the value of business being <strong>do</strong>ne <strong>and</strong>trying to identify the balance between cash in circulation <strong>and</strong> depos<strong>it</strong>smobilised, as well as the proportion of these depos<strong>it</strong>s that might beavailable for lending to the private sector (on the grounds that if depos<strong>it</strong>sare pre<strong>do</strong>minantly funding the state they cannot be creating <strong>access</strong>iblefinance for enterprise). This data mining exercise has been <strong>do</strong>ne inthe context of the present project for 163 countries 13 accounting for95% of the world’s population. The financial data was taken from IMFInternational Financial Statistics <strong>and</strong> merged w<strong>it</strong>h GDP, population <strong>and</strong>price data from World Bank World Development Indicators, to allowcomparisons of depos<strong>it</strong>s mobilised per head of population.The results of the analysis are presented in the tables <strong>and</strong> charts at theend of this chapter. They s<strong>how</strong> a clear set of benchmarks regarding thebalance of cash in circulation <strong>and</strong> depos<strong>it</strong>s mobilised <strong>and</strong> these can beused to grade countries as to where they lie in the spectrum from therepressed <strong>access</strong> typical of poor developing countries through the firstintermediate stages of broadening <strong>access</strong> before moving towards the full<strong>access</strong> typical of the advanced economies discussed in the l<strong>it</strong>erature survey.The hyperinflation, currency instabil<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> recurrent banking crises thatcharacterized the first stages of trans<strong>it</strong>ion to a market economy in theearly 1990s wiped out up to 95% of the real value of <strong>savings</strong> mobilised<strong>and</strong> recycled as cred<strong>it</strong> under the old regime of monobanking systems.<strong>What</strong> has happened since then has given fascinating insights into <strong>how</strong><strong>access</strong> can be rebuilt, w<strong>it</strong>h a very wide spectrum of experience to observe.The first stage has always been to restore a more normal balancebetween cash in circulation <strong>and</strong> high-turnover transactions balances inshort-term bank depos<strong>it</strong>s. During this phase, the rise in the ratio ofdepos<strong>it</strong>s to GDP essentially reflects reductions in the ratio of cash to GDP.Very often this involves a move away from settling commercial transactionsw<strong>it</strong>h hard currency cash towards local currency <strong>and</strong> bank transfers.During the first stage money stays in the accounts for as short a time aspossible <strong>and</strong> circulation is <strong>do</strong>minated by a few large players (often veryrich individuals). As economies stabilise, <strong>and</strong> their economic base broadensmore people get drawn into the process of proper monetary exchange.Better paid professionals in particular start to use their bank accounts formore than just receiving salaries <strong>and</strong> drawing them out as cash. During thissecond stage money stays in accounts for longer even though transactionvolumes are growing, thus raising average balances. The ratio of depos<strong>it</strong>sto GDP rises faster than can just be explained by reductions in reliance oncash. The final stage is where people more generally but also enterprisescome to rely on their bank accounts as a store of value. In this stage cashto depos<strong>it</strong> ratios as well as depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratios are heading towardsadvanced economy levels.The basis for this model is the experience of the previously very high<strong>access</strong> countries of the Soviet Bloc in Central <strong>and</strong> Eastern Europe. In all ofthese countries most individuals <strong>and</strong> all enterprises would trad<strong>it</strong>ionallyhave had a bank account <strong>and</strong> used <strong>it</strong> regularly for formal transactionseven if barter <strong>and</strong> countertrade were becoming significant aspects ofeconomic activ<strong>it</strong>y.13 In fact full data records were created for 175 countries but a number of these wereexcluded from the analysis as the bulk of their banking activ<strong>it</strong>y is offshore business <strong>and</strong> theindicators calculated bear no relationship to the levels of <strong>access</strong> offered to these <strong>banks</strong>’<strong>do</strong>mestic customers.6869


Figure 7: Use of cash versus depos<strong>it</strong>s – link to the roleof the banking system90%80%70%60%50%40%30%20%10%0%0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% 120% 140% 160% 180% 200%Figure 8: Use of cash versus depos<strong>it</strong>s – link to customer type90%80%70%60%50%11Growth from transactions movingfrom cash to bank transfers2Growth increasingly from moneysticking around longer in accounts3Growth comes from bankaccounts as a store of valueTotal household & enterprise depos<strong>it</strong>s as a % GDP (mid-2002)Banking system only really used by budget agencies,large corporations <strong>and</strong> high net worth individualsThe two charts on the previous page put the two indicators of cash versusdepos<strong>it</strong>s <strong>and</strong> depos<strong>it</strong>s versus GDP into a framework for grading <strong>access</strong> –first in terms of <strong>how</strong> customers use the banking system: e.g. are they using<strong>it</strong> merely for transactions or to store wealth? (Fig. 7) <strong>and</strong> secondly whouses <strong>it</strong>: e.g. large agencies <strong>and</strong> richer individuals versus the mass of thepopulation (Fig. 8).The zoning s<strong>how</strong>n can be used to set thresholds for the three grades of<strong>access</strong> (by type of use <strong>and</strong> by type of user) as discussed above. In add<strong>it</strong>ion<strong>it</strong> is helpful in interpreting the data to introduce a third variable, namelyper-cap<strong>it</strong>a depos<strong>it</strong>s adjusted for differences in prices, helps us to refinethe grading of individual countries.The values for these indicators suggest s<strong>how</strong> that to move from repressed<strong>access</strong> (where the proportion of the population having some sort of bankaccount <strong>and</strong> being able to use <strong>it</strong> will be less than 20%) typically requiresa depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio in the 10 to 20% range depending on the ratio ofcash to depos<strong>it</strong>s (the higher this is, the higher the ratio of depos<strong>it</strong>s of GDPmust be to move into the intermediate stage). It would be difficult to gradea country as having anything other than “repressed” <strong>access</strong> if the ratio ofcash to depos<strong>it</strong>s was much above 30%. The thresholds for being gradedas moving towards full <strong>access</strong> are similarly structured, but w<strong>it</strong>h depos<strong>it</strong>sin the 20-40% range when measured relative to GDP <strong>and</strong> cash to depos<strong>it</strong>ratios <strong>do</strong>wn below 20%. In certain countries where these two ratiosmight suggest a higher grading but per-cap<strong>it</strong>a depos<strong>it</strong>s are much lowerthan comparable countries in the region, a country has sometimes been<strong>do</strong>wngraded. This combination is often an indicator of a banking systemfocused on the international trading needs of an economically significantbut rather tightly defined corporate el<strong>it</strong>e. An example of this would beKenya – a country that might otherwise be graded as in the intermediatephase between repressed <strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> moving towards full <strong>access</strong>.40%30%20%10%2Banking becoming <strong>access</strong>ible to professionals<strong>and</strong> upper-end of mass-middle market3Banking sector growth onlycompatible w<strong>it</strong>h greater <strong>access</strong>0%0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% 120% 140% 160% 180% 200%Total household & enterprise depos<strong>it</strong>s as a % GDP (mid-2002)7071


Figure 9: Use of cash versus depos<strong>it</strong>s – implied level of <strong>access</strong>90%80%70%60%50%40%30%20%10%0%1WAfr MEUTanzaniaColombiaBrazil[Both][0.4]2[Both][


Taking all the <strong>savings</strong> bank elements of this together creates a muchsounder estimate of around 1.1 billion <strong>access</strong>ible accounts at postal <strong>and</strong>non-postal <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> 15 out of a total 1.4 billion <strong>access</strong>ible accountsat all <strong>do</strong>uble-bottom line inst<strong>it</strong>utions. The make-up of this total, butdifferentiating between who mobilises <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> who creates cred<strong>it</strong>s, isillustrated below:Figure 10: Suppliers of <strong>access</strong>ible accounts in developing/trans<strong>it</strong>ion economiesSavings / Payments Accounts= 1300 millionLoan Accounts= 190 millionThe data s<strong>how</strong>n above almost certainly understates the involvement of<strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> in the market for <strong>access</strong>ible cred<strong>it</strong> – non-postal <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong>across the developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economy world typically recycle halfof depos<strong>it</strong>s mobilised as cred<strong>it</strong>s <strong>and</strong> half of WSBI’s membership in thesecountries run some sort of specialist microcred<strong>it</strong> scheme. In any case thedistinction between general <strong>savings</strong> bank lending <strong>and</strong> microcred<strong>it</strong> is fairlyfungible. Microentrepreneurs across the world will often use consumer<strong>and</strong> mortgage loans to finance their business <strong>and</strong> the average loan sizefor the whole portfolio of WSBI members reporting loan accountnumbers is the same or less in Central Europe <strong>and</strong> Central & SouthernAmerica as the average loan size of specialist microfinance un<strong>it</strong>s in thesame regions (for Asia, <strong>how</strong>ever, <strong>it</strong> is significantly higher).Private bankm-f schemesMFIs / C.unions/ Co-opsOther publicpurpose <strong>banks</strong>Savings<strong>banks</strong>Private bankm-f schemesData on the above basis is available for inst<strong>it</strong>utions in some 130 developing<strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies <strong>and</strong> allows countries to be ranked in terms of<strong>access</strong>ible accounts per head of population as follows:Figure 11: Spectrum of <strong>access</strong> as s<strong>how</strong>n by <strong>access</strong>ible accountsper adultNote that the total number of <strong>access</strong>ible account relationships is lessthan the sum of depos<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong> loan accounts to avoid <strong>do</strong>uble countingcombined depos<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong> loan relationships.<strong>What</strong> is interesting in this analysis is the marked asymmetry between whomobilises <strong>savings</strong> services <strong>and</strong> who creates cred<strong>it</strong>. This difference is lessmarked if one looks at public purpose <strong>banks</strong> as a whole, i.e. <strong>savings</strong><strong>banks</strong> plus mostly publicly-owned agricultural <strong>and</strong> development <strong>banks</strong>.Together they service five out six <strong>access</strong>ible <strong>savings</strong>/payments accounts<strong>and</strong> provide four out of six <strong>access</strong>ible loan accounts. It is interesting alsoto note that, w<strong>it</strong>hin the data on loan accounts, <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> provide atleast as many <strong>access</strong>ible loans as specialist MFIs, cred<strong>it</strong> unions <strong>and</strong> cooperativescombined.15 Compared to CGAP’s original estimates of 320 million postal <strong>savings</strong> accounts (all deemed<strong>access</strong>ible) <strong>and</strong> 150 million non-postal <strong>savings</strong> accounts targeted at the market below thatserved by commercial <strong>banks</strong>.74Savings <strong>banks</strong>Other publicpurpose <strong>banks</strong>MFIs / C.unions/ Co-opsAccessible accounts / adult2.52.01.51.00.50.0REPRESSED ACCESSINTERMEDIATE PHASEFULLACCESSThe chart above has been zoned using the same target cr<strong>it</strong>eria as wasused for the monetisation data – i.e repressed <strong>access</strong> indicates less thanone <strong>access</strong>ible account for every fifth adult, an intermediate phase whereevery third or fourth adult has an account <strong>and</strong> moving towards full <strong>access</strong>once at least every second adult has an account.➜75


The dark line s<strong>how</strong>s total <strong>access</strong>ible accounts per adult <strong>and</strong> the greycolumns underneath s<strong>how</strong> <strong>access</strong>ible accounts at public-purpose <strong>banks</strong>(expressed as total numbers of accounts divided by the total adultpopulation). Each column represents a separate country. The wh<strong>it</strong>e spacebetween the dark line <strong>and</strong> the grey columns represents <strong>access</strong>ible accountsat specialist microfinance un<strong>it</strong>s <strong>and</strong> commun<strong>it</strong>y-based inst<strong>it</strong>utions such ascred<strong>it</strong> unions <strong>and</strong> co-operatives combined.Again the chart s<strong>how</strong>s <strong>how</strong> important <strong>savings</strong> or other public purpose<strong>banks</strong> are to the provision of <strong>access</strong>ible finance for all – there are very fewdeveloping <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies that are moving towards or alreadyhave full <strong>access</strong>, which <strong>do</strong> not have a strong <strong>savings</strong> or other public-purposebanking movement. Indeed <strong>it</strong> would seem that specialist microfinanceonly ever subst<strong>it</strong>utes for <strong>savings</strong> banking in countries w<strong>it</strong>h repressedlevels of <strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> that beyond this <strong>it</strong> becomes a complementary activ<strong>it</strong>ythat, as already noted above, is often conducted by <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> just asmuch as by specialist microfinance un<strong>it</strong>s. Where specialist microfinance<strong>and</strong> commun<strong>it</strong>y based <strong>access</strong> <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> frequently subst<strong>it</strong>ute for <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong>other public-purpose banking is in economies disrupted by war or otheracute civil disruption. Over half of the developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economiescovered by the chart above that have very repressed <strong>access</strong> (i.e. not evenone <strong>access</strong>ible account for every tenth adult) <strong>and</strong> no <strong>savings</strong> or otherpublic-purpose bank – i.e. entirely wh<strong>it</strong>e space below the line in the chartabove – have suffered at some time in this way during the decade or two.This analysis is encouraging regarding potential <strong>access</strong> across the developing<strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economy world but also challenging:■76Overall there is far more of a platform for <strong>access</strong> than thought to existeven a year ago – 1.4 billion account relationships identified in thisstudy (<strong>and</strong> WSBI [2005]) compared to 750 million in CGAP [2004] <strong>and</strong>the talk of only 50 million people w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>access</strong> to microcred<strong>it</strong> at whenthe UN Year of Microcred<strong>it</strong> was being planned a year or two earlier.At this level there are enough <strong>access</strong>ible accounts for roughly every2.4 adults across the developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economy world. If thiswas spread evenly across countries <strong>it</strong> would <strong>mean</strong> enough for mosthouseholds to have an account, but <strong>it</strong> is in fact spread very unevenlyw<strong>it</strong>h intermediate to high levels of <strong>access</strong> in a few countries w<strong>it</strong>h largepopulations (China, India, In<strong>do</strong>nesia <strong>and</strong> Russia) biasing up theaverage significantly.■Because of the uneven distribution of <strong>access</strong>ible accounts, the betterthan expected overall availabil<strong>it</strong>y hides very repressed levels of <strong>access</strong>in many developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ional economies, where less than onein five adults has an account at inst<strong>it</strong>utions designed to be <strong>access</strong>ible.The benef<strong>it</strong> of using this analysis to track <strong>access</strong> is that accounts at<strong>access</strong>ible inst<strong>it</strong>utions are clearly a more direct indicator than monetaryvolumes. Nevertheless, <strong>it</strong> <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> have weaknesses. First, <strong>it</strong> is a one-off analysisthat is not particularly easy to keep current. Perhaps more importantly, ina not insignificant minor<strong>it</strong>y of countries <strong>it</strong> s<strong>how</strong>s some countries ashaving l<strong>it</strong>tle or no <strong>access</strong> where in fact they have relatively developedcommercial banking systems that <strong>do</strong> reach <strong>do</strong>wn at least into the massmiddle market.The approach taken in this paper is therefore to use the analysis based onmonetary volumes (i.e. depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP <strong>and</strong> cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratios) to modifyat the margins the analysis based on <strong>access</strong>ible account penetration.Table 7 below gives the results of this merged approach. Countries aregraded by the number of <strong>access</strong>ible accounts per adult <strong>and</strong> groupedaccording to whether <strong>access</strong> is coming (a) pre<strong>do</strong>minantly from specialistmicrofinance un<strong>it</strong>s, cred<strong>it</strong> unions <strong>and</strong> co-operatives, (b) pre<strong>do</strong>minantly from<strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> other public-purpose <strong>banks</strong> or (c) where commercial<strong>banks</strong> might also be playing a significant role in providing <strong>access</strong>. In thelatter case, where the number of <strong>access</strong>ible accounts per adult is relativelylow but monetary indicators suggest higher levels of <strong>access</strong>, then thecountries to which this applies are s<strong>how</strong>n first in bold, where the numberof <strong>access</strong>ible accounts per adult would suggest they should appear, <strong>and</strong>second in normal text where monetary volumes suggest they should be.The arrows indicate <strong>how</strong> far up the <strong>access</strong>ibil<strong>it</strong>y ranking the monetaryvolume data move some countries.Having made these adjustments then, of the 130 developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ioneconomies that can be addressed in this way, more than half the sample– some 74 countries – display repressed levels of <strong>access</strong> where less thanone in five adults will have an account. By contrast barely a third of thisnumber – some 26 developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies – will be movingtowards or already have full <strong>access</strong>, where at least every second adult<strong>and</strong> therefore most households will have an account. This leaves some30 countries in the intermediate phase where between a quarter <strong>and</strong> athird of adults will have an account. Having graded countries in this way,<strong>it</strong> is then possible to calculate average indicators of <strong>access</strong> for differentregions, <strong>and</strong> compare these for groups of countries w<strong>it</strong>h different levelsof <strong>access</strong>.77


It is also possible to compare development indicators for these same groupsw<strong>it</strong>hin regions. This is <strong>do</strong>ne in Tables 8 <strong>and</strong> 9 below.Table 7: Summary grading of countries by merged metho<strong>do</strong>f assessing <strong>access</strong>Countries w<strong>it</strong>h signsof some significant <strong>access</strong>via comm. <strong>banks</strong>Savings <strong>and</strong> other publicpurposebank providing bulkof <strong>access</strong>Bulk of <strong>access</strong> via specialistMFIs, cred<strong>it</strong> unions, co-ops, etc78Brunei, Djibouti, Israel, Kuwa<strong>it</strong>,Qatar, S. Arabia & UAEChad, Somalia & TurkmenistanCountries w<strong>it</strong>h no identified<strong>access</strong>ible accounts per adultArgentina, Estonia, Libya,L<strong>it</strong>huania, Oman, Albania,Bhutan, Syria, FYROM,Lesotho, Sao Tome P., Maur<strong>it</strong>ius,Jordan, Mexico, Guyana,Nicaragua, Costa Rica,Peru & South AfricaLibya, Belarus, Yemen, Iraq,Sudan, Zambia, Tajikistan, SerbiaMontenegro, Maur<strong>it</strong>ania,Azerbaijan, Uzbekistan,Cen. African Rep., Myanmar,Comoros & CambodiaAfghanistan, Lao PDR, Liberia,WB&Gaza, Er<strong>it</strong>rea, Mozambique,Timor-Leste, Venezuela, Mol<strong>do</strong>va,Sierra Leone, Armenia, Georgia,Kyrgyz R., Bosnia H., Nigeria,Guinea, Ethiopia, Swazil<strong>and</strong>,Ghana, Burundi, Ug<strong>and</strong>a, Nepal,El Salva<strong>do</strong>r, Gambia & MalawiCountries w<strong>it</strong>h only 0.01 ~ 0.10identified <strong>access</strong>ible accountsper adult REPRESSED ACCESS Honduras, Iran, Kenya, Latvia,Namibia, Paraguay, Philippines,Slovenia, Suriname & SenegalAlgeria, Cameroon, Pakistan,Tanzania, Ukraine, Colombia, &Cote d'IvoireRw<strong>and</strong>a, Madagascar, Congo,Burkina Faso, Togo & GuatemalaCountries w<strong>it</strong>h only 0.10 ~ 0.20identified <strong>access</strong>ible accounts peradultArgentina, Brunei, Djibouti,Estonia, Kenya, Libya, L<strong>it</strong>huania,Mexico, S.Arabia, FYROM,Namibia & Peru realloacted plusBelize, Croatia, Uruguay, TurkeyVietnam, Gabon, Brazil,Zimbabwe, Romania, Niger, Mali,India, Mongolia, Botswana,Kazakhstan, Angola, Tunisia,Morocco & Egypt.Ecua<strong>do</strong>r, Benin, Bangladesh &In<strong>do</strong>nesiaCountries w<strong>it</strong>h 0.20 ~ 0.50identified <strong>access</strong>ible accounts peradultINTERMEDIATECroatia, Jordan, Oman, Kuwa<strong>it</strong>,Philippines, Qatar, Slovenia,S.Africa, UAE & Uruguayall reallocatedPol<strong>and</strong>, China, Kazakhstan, Cuba,Korea, Bolivia, Russia, Malaysia,Czech R., Bulgaria & ChileCountries w<strong>it</strong>h 0.50 ~ 1.00identified <strong>access</strong>ible accounts peradultTOWARDSFULLAll advanced economiesplus Israel reallocatedCape Verde, Thail<strong>and</strong>, SlovakRepublic, Sri Lanka & HungaryCountries w<strong>it</strong>h more than one<strong>access</strong>ible account per adultFULLNOTES: All small isl<strong>and</strong> states <strong>and</strong> known offshore centres excluded.Table 8: Summary indicators of <strong>access</strong> across different regionsAdvanced econ. Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Accessible a/c per adult91% 7% not calculatedAll relatively high <strong>access</strong>Towards full <strong>access</strong> Intermediate stage RepressedMid-East & Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratioNorth Africa 73% 51% 34%Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio6% 17% 10%Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult0.02 0.38 0.11East & Southern Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratioAfrica 58% 18% 18%Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio4% 12% 30%Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult0.10 0.20 0.05West & Central Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratioAfrica 61% 14% 18%Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio12% 42% 31%Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult0.80 0.25 0.05Central & Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratioSouth America 38% 25% 22%Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio7% 12% 14%Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult0.76 0.15 0.11Central Europe Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio(Incl. new EU) 42% 20% 22%Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio16% 16% 37%Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult0.94 0.24 0.05Russia <strong>and</strong> Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratioOther CIS 20% 23% 18%Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio33% 22% 50%Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult1.73 0.03 0.05South & East Asia Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio Depos<strong>it</strong> to GDP ratio131% 48% 43%Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio Cash to depos<strong>it</strong> ratio8% 18% 18%Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult Accessible a/c per adult0.63 0.26 0.0979


Table 9: Development indicators for countries grouped by region<strong>and</strong> <strong>access</strong>Advanced econ. Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Rural: Urban ratio PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a0% 0.31 29647All relatively high <strong>access</strong>Towards full <strong>access</strong> Intermediate stage RepressedMid-East & Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracyNorth Africa 14% 42% 30%Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio0.16 0.79 0.77PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a16,979 7,196 6,851East & Southern Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracyAfrica 15% 16% 43%Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio0.75 1.63 2.95PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a13,182 2,745 1,582West & Central Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracyAfrica 75% 41%Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio2.01 1.42PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a1,920 1,947Central & Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracySouth America 7% 11% 14%Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio0.25 0.24 0.42PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a9,113 10,286 7,060Central Europe Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy(Incl. new EU) 1% 2% 0%Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio0.56 0.79 0.50PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a12,434 7,431 10,577Russia <strong>and</strong> Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracyOther CIS 1% no data 1%Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio0.41 0.69 0.69PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a8,534 7,223 4,493South & East Asia Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy Adult Ill<strong>it</strong>eracy14% 40% 40%Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio Rural: Urban ratio1.48 2.30 1.54PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a PPP adj. GDP per cap<strong>it</strong>a5,841 3,415 3,65180These add<strong>it</strong>ional socio-economic variables – taken from World Bank WorldDevelopment Indicators <strong>and</strong> UNDP Millennium Development Goal Indicators– allow some conclusions to be drawn on whether lack of <strong>access</strong> isaddressable w<strong>it</strong>hin a narrow banking system context (e.g. by openingmore bank branches) or is a function of a wider lack of economicdevelopment. When these indicators are presented on a region-by-regionbasis they reveal a fairly systematic relationship between acutelyrepressed <strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> wider under-development.There is always going to be some circular<strong>it</strong>y to this type of argument– banking systems in poor economies are always likely to be small relativeto GDP <strong>and</strong> this makes them too costly to support the process ofdevelopment for all but a privileged el<strong>it</strong>e. Nevertheless our approach <strong>and</strong>the results obtained <strong>do</strong> have implications for the policy agenda, whichwill be explored more fully in the next two chapters. Two apparentrelationships should be investigated further:■ the correlation, at least for some regions, between the low levels of<strong>access</strong> in some poorer countries <strong>and</strong> ill<strong>it</strong>eracy; <strong>and</strong>■ a similar partial correlation between the balance of rural versus urb<strong>and</strong>wellers w<strong>it</strong>hin the population.Both suggest that new models of reaching people may help <strong>access</strong>.Looking at regional differences five conclusions emerge:■ Sub-Saharan Africa is a long way behind other regions in terms ofexp<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>access</strong> (although much, but by no <strong>mean</strong>s all, of this is areflection of the extremes of poverty seen there).■ Asia is pretty well advanced in this respect. This is particularly true ofthe rapidly industrialising countries in that region but also of thegeneral<strong>it</strong>y of developing Asia.■ The more advanced trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies of Central Europe haveprogressed extremely well in rebuilding real <strong>access</strong> after the hugedeclines of the early 1990s.■ However, most CIS countries, w<strong>it</strong>h the exception of Russia, lag farbehind in this process.■ Central <strong>and</strong> South America have made surprisingly l<strong>it</strong>tle progress insp<strong>it</strong>e of relatively robust economic bases. This is particularly true of thelarger countries in that region.81


Much greater regional detail is available from the two separate studiescompleted for WSBI by the authors of this study (WSBI [2004] <strong>and</strong> [2005]).Four main issues for further research are:■ to integrate emerging data on account numbers at commercial <strong>banks</strong>coming from surveys of regulator by World Bank, which is underwaynow <strong>and</strong> should yield results in early 2006;■ to <strong>do</strong> more detailed survey work w<strong>it</strong>h different types of <strong>savings</strong> bankto assess <strong>how</strong> far their reach extends across different socio-economicsegments of the populations they serve, particularly the poor;■ to try <strong>and</strong> differentiate w<strong>it</strong>hin the analysis between household <strong>and</strong>enterprise use of banking services (which will require <strong>access</strong>ingindividual central bank data rather than the large multilateraldatabases used so far);■ <strong>and</strong> to address, using banking sector prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y data (e<strong>it</strong>her systemwideor better still bank-by-bank), the cr<strong>it</strong>ical issue of the cost of<strong>access</strong> in different regions.4. PUBLIC POLICYAND BANK RESPONSESTO ISSUES OF ACCESSA. OverviewThe nature of problems w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>access</strong> in advanced industrial countries differcompared to those in poorer developing economies. The policy responsestend to be different as well. In advanced industrial economies policy toimprove <strong>access</strong> focuses partly on (a) making sure the banking system <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong>not leave some parts of the <strong>do</strong>mestic population behind as <strong>it</strong> pursuesmore prof<strong>it</strong>able segments of the market at home <strong>and</strong> abroad <strong>and</strong> (b)trying to strengthen non-bank alternatives for those who are no longereffectively served by <strong>banks</strong>. By contrast the thrust of policy in poorerdeveloping countries now seems to be going the other way. So far – (a)most focus has been on non-bank outreach to reach the bulk of thepopulation <strong>and</strong> has involved (b) disappointments w<strong>it</strong>h a lack of financialself-sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y among microfinance programmes that is leading to are-examination of what role the formal banking system could play.B. Public policy measures to enhance individual <strong>access</strong>1. Advanced economiesMost OECD governments have introduced policies to try to improve<strong>access</strong> to financial services for poorer <strong>and</strong> vulnerable households.In many cases these interventions are of qu<strong>it</strong>e recent origin – the last5 years. The important exception <strong>and</strong> arguably the most substantial<strong>and</strong> long-lived set of policy measures to improve financial <strong>access</strong> arethose embodied in the US Commun<strong>it</strong>y Reinvestment Act (CRA) enactedby the US Congress in 1977 <strong>and</strong> revised in 1995. The details of theobjectives <strong>and</strong> modus oper<strong>and</strong>i of this Act are discussed below <strong>and</strong> inthe related box but the CRA approach is just one of three optionsopen to governments:8283


■■■The regulatory system can be used to direct but not m<strong>and</strong>ate <strong>banks</strong>to address the problem (<strong>and</strong> this is what might be described as theCRA model in the US);The author<strong>it</strong>ies can m<strong>and</strong>ate all <strong>banks</strong> to provide minimum bankingservices for otherwise excluded segments of the market (so-called“basic accounts”); orThey can rely on <strong>banks</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h a social comm<strong>it</strong>ment (in the legal formof e<strong>it</strong>her public <strong>banks</strong>, cooperatives or foundations) as for examplein the French, German <strong>and</strong> Spanish banking system <strong>and</strong>/or on whatare sometimes confusingly called “universal <strong>banks</strong>” offering veryrestricted retail services through the postal network.The CRA model is very much an American solution, not followedelsewhere <strong>and</strong> hence the main discussion of <strong>it</strong> in this paper is in abox below. Claims for <strong>it</strong>s success are contested but w<strong>it</strong>h ne<strong>it</strong>her sideestablishing a strong pos<strong>it</strong>ion. It is perhaps a classic American compromisebetween a comm<strong>it</strong>ment to free markets combined w<strong>it</strong>h the use of qu<strong>it</strong>esubstantial regulatory powers to protect the interest of individualsagainst those of large corporations. The CRA should not, moreover beseen in isolation. In 1999, the US Treasury Department launched amajor effort to pay all federal benef<strong>it</strong> payments, such as social secur<strong>it</strong>ybenef<strong>it</strong>s, electronically. One impediment to this in<strong>it</strong>iative was the largenumber of benef<strong>it</strong> recipients w<strong>it</strong>hout bank accounts. As a result, theTreasury urged <strong>banks</strong> to offer Electronic Transfer Accounts (ETAs).The Treasury offered to pay <strong>banks</strong> $12.60 for each ETA accountthey established for benef<strong>it</strong> recipients, <strong>and</strong> the Treasury specifieda minimum set of characteristics that these accounts must meet.The accounts could not cost account owners more than $3 a month,they could levy no fee for electronic depos<strong>it</strong>s coming from the federalgovernment, they could have no minimum balance requirement,<strong>and</strong> they had to perm<strong>it</strong> four free cash w<strong>it</strong>hdrawals per month.Although hundreds of <strong>banks</strong>, thrifts, <strong>and</strong> cred<strong>it</strong> unions agreed to offerthe accounts, usage rates are reportedly low.Box 5: The commun<strong>it</strong>y reinvestment act:objectives, methods <strong>and</strong> evaluationOriginsThe Commun<strong>it</strong>y Reinvestment Act (CRA) was enacted by the Congressin 1977 in order to encourage depos<strong>it</strong>ory inst<strong>it</strong>utions to help meet thecred<strong>it</strong> requirements of the commun<strong>it</strong>ies in which they operatedincluding low to moderate income neighbourhoods. The law specifiedthat such commun<strong>it</strong>y lending must be consistent w<strong>it</strong>h safe <strong>and</strong> soundbanking practises. In 1981 a Commun<strong>it</strong>y Affairs Office was set up byeach of the 12 Federal Reserve Banks. The Commun<strong>it</strong>y Affairs office aimwas to work w<strong>it</strong>h both the public <strong>and</strong> the depos<strong>it</strong>ory inst<strong>it</strong>utions toidentify cred<strong>it</strong> needs <strong>and</strong> existent gaps <strong>and</strong> find solutions to address thecommun<strong>it</strong>y’s cred<strong>it</strong> needs. Many hundreds of US <strong>banks</strong> now participatein the CRA in<strong>it</strong>iative <strong>and</strong> comply w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>it</strong>s requirements but 75% of thebusiness is performed by 500 larger <strong>banks</strong>.CRA ExaminersBoard of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (FRB) / The Office ofThrift Supervision (OTS)The Federal Depos<strong>it</strong> Insurance Corporation (FDIC) / Office of theComptroller of the Currency (OCC)Objectives- Encourage partnerships among public <strong>and</strong> private organisations tofulfil the cred<strong>it</strong> needs of low to medium income neighbourhoods.- Informing financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions <strong>and</strong> commun<strong>it</strong>y organisations on theavailabil<strong>it</strong>y of public <strong>and</strong> private commun<strong>it</strong>y development resources- Promoting an underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the CRA amongst individuals,commun<strong>it</strong>ies, <strong>and</strong> inst<strong>it</strong>utions.- Promoting <strong>and</strong> increasing the awareness of a commun<strong>it</strong>y’s needs <strong>and</strong>assets for development.8485


CRA RegulationThe major<strong>it</strong>y of the examining organisations conduct a CRA cred<strong>it</strong> ratingevery three years for national <strong>banks</strong>. However the Gramm-Leach-BlileyAct m<strong>and</strong>ates an extended examination cycle for smaller <strong>banks</strong>.Restructuring of the CRA examination now <strong>mean</strong>s that emphasis liesw<strong>it</strong>h the bank’s performance in making loans rather than the bank’sprocess for complying w<strong>it</strong>h CRA. The bank receives one of four possibleratings. These are: Outst<strong>and</strong>ing, Satisfactory, Needs Improvement orsubstantial non-compliance. Tests focus on the areas of lending (whichcarries greater weight than the others), service <strong>and</strong> the investment.The depos<strong>it</strong>ory inst<strong>it</strong>ution under examination may fall into one of fourcategories, large <strong>banks</strong> that exceed $250 million <strong>do</strong>llars of assets, small<strong>banks</strong> which hold under $250 million in assets, wholesale <strong>banks</strong>, <strong>and</strong>a more complex sub-group of <strong>banks</strong> that choose to be evaluatedunder a strategic plan option, where they are evaluated against apre-determined <strong>and</strong> approved set of CRA cr<strong>it</strong>eria.Bank EvaluationTo attain a CRA rating, the depos<strong>it</strong>ory inst<strong>it</strong>ution must be evaluatedregularly in order to assess <strong>it</strong>s abil<strong>it</strong>y to meet <strong>it</strong>s commun<strong>it</strong>y cred<strong>it</strong> needs.CRA examinations are conducted by the relevant federal agenciesresponsible for overseeing the depos<strong>it</strong>ory organisations in their respectiveregions. The abil<strong>it</strong>y of depos<strong>it</strong>ory inst<strong>it</strong>utions to meet their commun<strong>it</strong>ylending needs <strong>and</strong> thus acquire a favourable CRA rating is taken intoaccount when they seek to exp<strong>and</strong> through merger, acquis<strong>it</strong>ion <strong>and</strong>branching.Process EvaluationIn November 1999 the US Congress instructed the Federal Reserve Boardto undertake a comparative study of performance on CRA loanprogrammes. The study was asked explic<strong>it</strong>ly to look at the usefulness ofprior research <strong>and</strong> found that <strong>it</strong> was very lim<strong>it</strong>ed in scope focusingmainly on a small sub-set of loans made under affordable-home-loanprogrammes w<strong>it</strong>hin CRA. However, these studies did reveal largevariations in loan performance across individual banking inst<strong>it</strong>utions,depending on factors such as client location <strong>and</strong> also the specificapproaches used to extend CRA loans. The 1999 study reviewed theactiv<strong>it</strong>ies of the 500 largest <strong>banks</strong> accounting for 75% of all CRA loans.Response rates were relatively low (less than 30%) but revealed, amongothers, the following main conclusions:- Overall CRA lending has been prof<strong>it</strong>able or marginally prof<strong>it</strong>able formost <strong>banks</strong>- CRA-home-purchase <strong>and</strong> refinance lending was less prof<strong>it</strong>able <strong>and</strong>had generally worse (<strong>and</strong> certainly no better) delinquency rates thanmainstream lending in these categories- Larger <strong>banks</strong> s<strong>how</strong>ed a significant tendency to have lower prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>yCRA-lending (relative to their overall lending) than did smaller <strong>banks</strong>- SME loans via the CRA programme were prof<strong>it</strong>able for most <strong>banks</strong><strong>and</strong> differed very l<strong>it</strong>tle in terms of their delivery costs <strong>and</strong> prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>yas compared w<strong>it</strong>h mainstream SME lending.8687


88Finally, some government agencies <strong>and</strong> philanthropic organisationshave provided financial support to cred<strong>it</strong> unions <strong>and</strong> <strong>banks</strong> that have,as a main goal, the promotion of the economic development of low- <strong>and</strong>middle-income commun<strong>it</strong>ies. Such <strong>banks</strong>, cred<strong>it</strong> unions <strong>and</strong> venturecap<strong>it</strong>al firms are generically known as commun<strong>it</strong>y development financialinst<strong>it</strong>utions (CDFIs). Some are organised as not-for-prof<strong>it</strong> inst<strong>it</strong>utions<strong>and</strong> others as for-prof<strong>it</strong>, but to be classified as a CDFI a for-prof<strong>it</strong>organisation must be willing to lim<strong>it</strong> <strong>it</strong>s prof<strong>it</strong>s in order to achievecommun<strong>it</strong>y development goals.From 1997 onwards the Un<strong>it</strong>ed King<strong>do</strong>m government has made thefight against exclusion a high prior<strong>it</strong>y. However, <strong>it</strong> has a<strong>do</strong>pted anapproach based on mediation <strong>and</strong> consensus rather than on forcingimposed solutions such a universal banking obligation. The UKnotified to the EU various methods in the name of ‘universal bankingservices’ in July 2001. These measures were part of a drive to improve<strong>access</strong> to current accounts for the ‘un-banked’ <strong>and</strong> were also designedto reform the social secur<strong>it</strong>y benef<strong>it</strong> system by making <strong>it</strong> obligatory forall transactions to be paid through automated cred<strong>it</strong> transfers.The UK government proposed that Post Office Lim<strong>it</strong>ed, in collaborationw<strong>it</strong>h <strong>banks</strong> willing to take part in the scheme, should in the futureoffer basic bank accounts that are specifically tailored to the needs ofthose w<strong>it</strong>hout bank accounts. These bank accounts are free of charge<strong>and</strong> <strong>do</strong> not offer cred<strong>it</strong> facil<strong>it</strong>ies: the latter point avoiding the riskwhich is a major deterrent for people that choose to remain w<strong>it</strong>hout abank account. For those who still <strong>do</strong> not wish to open even this basicbank account, a Post Office Card Account (POCA) would be offered,which would be similar to the old system, but instead using a swipecard in place of the old paper order books <strong>and</strong> giro-cheques. This wouldbe expected to increase the numbers of state-pensioners <strong>and</strong> otherwelfare beneficiaries introduced into banking. However, POCA hasso far been used narrowly as a cash w<strong>it</strong>hdrawal system by mostbeneficiaries.In France legal arrangements exist to combat exclusion (e.g. theloi Aubry of 1998) <strong>and</strong> these recognise the right of all individualsto possess a bank account. Nonetheless <strong>it</strong> is estimated that around1 million vulnerable persons <strong>do</strong> not possess even a st<strong>and</strong>ard checkingaccount (Le Monde June 2004). In 1999 France inst<strong>it</strong>uted the idea ofa basic banking service for the most deprived households <strong>and</strong> lateradded procedures for personal bankruptcy to make <strong>it</strong> easer for highlyindebted families to get a second chance (the law Borloo of August 2003).So far the take- up of the basic banking service seems to have beendisappointing w<strong>it</strong>h the Bank of France estimating a take-up of only12,000 persons by 2003.This is attributed in part to a discriminatory att<strong>it</strong>ude on the part of themainstream French commercial <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> an increasingly drasticprof<strong>it</strong>-driven selection cr<strong>it</strong>eria for clients (Gloukoviezoff [2003]).The system works broadly as follows. All French <strong>banks</strong> have the right,the law mentioned above notw<strong>it</strong>hst<strong>and</strong>ing, to turn <strong>do</strong>wn anyoneseeking to open an account. But the rejected person can than contactthe Bank of France who will provide a named bank that will then beobligated to open an account for that person. Because this isunpopular w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>banks</strong>, one result has been that the battle againstexclusion has fallen squarely on the French postal network (via La Poste).Specifically La Poste reckons that one out of two persons on modestincomes are clients (mainly via pass-book accounts) although <strong>it</strong> hasonly about a 9% share of the financial services market as a whole.Sweden has also undertaken pro-active measures to address financialsector <strong>access</strong>. Commercial <strong>banks</strong> in Sweden are obliged to acceptdepos<strong>it</strong>s from the public, <strong>and</strong> therefore are obliged to open accounts.However, they are not obliged to provide associated payment services,a practice that has been condemned by the Financial SupervisoryBoard. The Post Office, by contrast, has always facil<strong>it</strong>ated over-thecountercash/payments transactions. Unfortunately, due to the rapidincrease in telephone <strong>and</strong> internet banking <strong>and</strong> the associated costreductions <strong>and</strong> the ending of cross-subsidies, these types of paymentservices have been declining in their availabil<strong>it</strong>y. This has caused a risein the cost of providing the services. In an effort to ensure uniform<strong>access</strong> to cash facil<strong>it</strong>ies, the Swedish government in 2001 proposedentrusting the State-owned Posten AB w<strong>it</strong>h a universal basic cashservice.Similarly, the government in Irel<strong>and</strong> has for some years been comm<strong>it</strong>tedto developing an information society <strong>and</strong> to use this to support theanti-poverty programme that was launched in 1997. In 2002 <strong>it</strong> wasdecided that a single regulatory author<strong>it</strong>y for financial services wouldmon<strong>it</strong>or <strong>and</strong> promote <strong>access</strong> to financial services from a c<strong>it</strong>izens’perspectives. The main measure taken by Irel<strong>and</strong> was the redevelopmentof the Post Office network, increasing country-wide <strong>access</strong> to counterservices, <strong>and</strong> in particular improve <strong>access</strong> for vulnerable people inremote areas.89


2. Developing economiesThe same basic options present themselves to the governments ofdeveloping countries but w<strong>it</strong>h much more focus on the third option -relying on social <strong>and</strong> public sector inst<strong>it</strong>utions to fill the supply gaps inthe market.The exception is South Africa where something rather like AmericanCRA approach is being tried. Under the wider auspices of the BlackEconomic Empowerment (BEE) programme <strong>and</strong> the more sectorspecificFinance Sector Charter, the big four <strong>banks</strong> have come togetherw<strong>it</strong>h the South African Post-Office (SAPO) <strong>and</strong> a number of smallermass-<strong>access</strong> proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> to address the issue of improving <strong>access</strong>for the half of black adults that have no bank account or transactionsmechanisms 16 . The focus is on developing very basic but functionalFirst Order Financial Products (FORFPs). To qualify as giving effective<strong>access</strong>, these products must be delivered through an <strong>access</strong>iblegeographic footprint (no more than 20km to the nearest <strong>access</strong> point),offer sufficient range <strong>and</strong> choice, be appropriate <strong>and</strong> affordable to thetarget market as well as user-friendly in their design, delivery <strong>and</strong>marketing. Two examples of such products are the Mzansi Account(for <strong>savings</strong>) <strong>and</strong> the Mzansi Transfer Product (for transactions) describedin Nedbank [2004]. These will have common terms across all participating<strong>banks</strong>, will be capable of being carried on existing bank IT systems,<strong>and</strong> will settle between <strong>banks</strong> using the existing cred<strong>it</strong>/deb<strong>it</strong> cardSASw<strong>it</strong>ch system. The st<strong>and</strong>ardisation of terms <strong>and</strong> the use of existingIT platforms are intended to allow marginal cost pricing so thatexisting better-off customers will continue to pay for an operatingplatform they already use, leaving Mzansi customers to pay only forthe genuine extra costs of processing their own business.For other developing countries, the focus has trad<strong>it</strong>ionally been ondeveloping specific inst<strong>it</strong>utional arrangements for <strong>foster</strong>ing <strong>access</strong>.In the early post-colonial era this often focused on setting up specialist<strong>banks</strong> or nationalising <strong>and</strong> localising inher<strong>it</strong>ed <strong>banks</strong>. The most commonvehicle for providing individual <strong>access</strong> was a specialist lim<strong>it</strong>ed-m<strong>and</strong>atebank that could only gather <strong>savings</strong> depos<strong>it</strong>s <strong>and</strong> process certainlim<strong>it</strong>ed transactions. Savers depos<strong>it</strong>s in these inst<strong>it</strong>utions weresupposedly protected by very strict lim<strong>it</strong>ations on <strong>how</strong> funds could beinvested (usually lim<strong>it</strong>ed to “safe” government loans <strong>and</strong> secur<strong>it</strong>ies).16 The whole in<strong>it</strong>iative is given further impetus by high levels of crime w<strong>it</strong>hin South Africa,which discourages employers of even low-wage black workers from continuing paymentof wages in cash.A more restrictive version of this approach was to set up a national<strong>savings</strong> scheme, again w<strong>it</strong>h very strict lim<strong>it</strong>s on <strong>how</strong> funds mobilisedcould be used. Classic examples are Bansefi in Mexico (accounting forabout one sixth of all bank accounts <strong>and</strong> <strong>savings</strong> accounts in Mexico),the Government Savings Bank in Thail<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Indian small <strong>savings</strong>schemes formulated by the Ministry of Finance <strong>and</strong> administered bythe National Savings Inst<strong>it</strong>ute.The capac<strong>it</strong>y of many of these inst<strong>it</strong>utions to meet the needs of theirdeveloping economies stagnated through the 1970s, often as <strong>do</strong>norsupport diminished <strong>and</strong> <strong>savings</strong> mobilised were diverted to less<strong>and</strong> less viable projects. Through the 1980s <strong>and</strong> 1990s, problemsw<strong>it</strong>h sustaining these compromised <strong>banks</strong> or schemes forced manygovernments to surrender the issue of improving <strong>access</strong> to NGOs <strong>and</strong>the emerging microfinance industry. In many ways much governmentpolicy came to be seen as obstructive to financial <strong>access</strong>, usuallybecause of repressive financial regulations that capped interest rates,imposed burdensome reserve requirements or distorted the directionof lending through targeted cred<strong>it</strong> schemes. All of these were seen asgetting in the way of effective bank intermediation.By the late 1990s, <strong>how</strong>ever, the agenda seemed to be changing againbecause of dissatisfaction w<strong>it</strong>h (a) the so-called “apex organisations”that channel funds from large <strong>do</strong>nors to small NGO-based microfinanceschemes <strong>and</strong> (b) the lack of financial self-sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y of many smallerschemes when <strong>do</strong>nor funds run out. Because both of these are lessproblematic in a successful bank-based microlending scheme, therehas been growing interest in <strong>banks</strong> as channels for microfinance.The change in pos<strong>it</strong>ion is probably best summarised by CGAP FocusNote 12 [1998] on Commercial Banks in Microfinance. This summariseda conference sponsored by USAID <strong>and</strong> a study by Baydas, Graham <strong>and</strong>Valenzuela [1998]. The main themes were that <strong>banks</strong> were structurallysu<strong>it</strong>ed for microfinance (they were regulated, properly controlled <strong>and</strong>had their own funding sources) but that they were held back byinternal misconceptions about the qual<strong>it</strong>y of microfinance. The keyrecommendations on the policy side were that <strong>do</strong>nors should be:■ Urging governments to eliminate repressive financial regulationsdescribed above as these changes will help microfinance lenderscompete in open markets as well as cover operating costs, risks,<strong>and</strong> the opportun<strong>it</strong>y costs of cap<strong>it</strong>al.9091


■■Developing <strong>and</strong> encouraging the a<strong>do</strong>ption of prudential regulatoryframeworks that recognise the special nature of microfinance.High legal reserve requirements, burdensome reporting requirements,inappropriate cr<strong>it</strong>eria for loan portfolio classification <strong>and</strong> provisioning,restrictions on the volume of unsecured (non-collateralised) loans,<strong>and</strong> inappropriate operational cost ratios are some of the elementsthat need to be modified to su<strong>it</strong> microfinance operations.Supporting dialogues between <strong>banks</strong> providing microfinanceservices <strong>and</strong> regulators to help educate supervisory author<strong>it</strong>ies onthe differences between microfinance <strong>and</strong> trad<strong>it</strong>ional banking.C. Public policy measures to enhance enterprise <strong>access</strong>1. Advanced economiesTo the degree that the CRA in the Un<strong>it</strong>ed States functions to improveor at least sustain individual <strong>access</strong>, <strong>it</strong> also <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> so for enterprises.The clearest demonstration of an active policy to <strong>foster</strong> SME <strong>access</strong>to finance is probably the European Union Lisbon Agenda <strong>and</strong> therelated Multiannual programme for enterprise <strong>and</strong> entrepreneurship(MAP). This is regularly reviewed <strong>and</strong> the latest description is containedin a European Commission [2003] working paper. Financial support forSMEs can be broken <strong>do</strong>wn into five main str<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> these aresummarised in the table below, w<strong>it</strong>h some indication of resourcesdevoted to each str<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the benef<strong>it</strong> gained by SMEs:Table 10: MAP summary of financial instruments for supportingEuropean SMEsEIB Global loansEIF Guarantees*SME Guarantee Facil<strong>it</strong>y*EIF Venture cap<strong>it</strong>al instrumentso/w EIF own resourcesEIB m<strong>and</strong>ated resourcesETF Start-up Facil<strong>it</strong>yOther Programmeso/w Seed cap<strong>it</strong>al actionJEV95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05€22.5bn€1.3bn€9.8bn€0.2bn€2.0bn€0.2bn€0.1bn€8.0bn€0.1bn€0.0bnThe nearly €40 billion of finance provided or facil<strong>it</strong>ated by theseprogrammes between their inception <strong>and</strong> end-2002 was augmentedby another €5-6 billion of comm<strong>it</strong>ments under other programmes.Taken together these funds are estimated to have benef<strong>it</strong>ed just shortof one quarter of a million enterprises or about 1% of the potentialuniverse of SMEs operating in the EU. In add<strong>it</strong>ion to this would beMember States’ own schemes (particularly guarantee schemes) whichalthough distributing some of the EU support described above, alsogenerate their own flow of finance to enterprises.2. Developing economiesAgain, the same basic options present themselves to the governmentsof developing countries but <strong>it</strong> is much harder to gather data on suchschemes. In add<strong>it</strong>ion to this, the same sorts of flows of lending fromMFIs described for individuals in Section 2 will also be going tomicroenterprises (w<strong>it</strong>h the two very often indistinguishable where theymost directly relate to very small scale activ<strong>it</strong>y).D. Banking sector responses to financial exclusionin advanced economiesAs is clear from the previous section, outside the “proxim<strong>it</strong>y” bank sector(discussed separately in Chapter 6) most banking sector responses toproblems of individual <strong>access</strong> to financial services appear to have beenreactive to public policy rather than pro-active. In the l<strong>it</strong>erature on <strong>access</strong>this is seen as a feature of the pressures of globalisation <strong>and</strong> <strong>banks</strong>’ desireto sustain shareholder returns in an environment of disinflation <strong>and</strong>declining margins – <strong>banks</strong> <strong>do</strong>ing the minimum to allay public policyconcerns about growing exclusion while pursuing rationalisation of branchnetworks, marketing prior<strong>it</strong>ies <strong>and</strong> product cross-subsidies, is a commontheme. In part, this is a reflection of the bias in the debate about <strong>access</strong>in advanced economies w<strong>it</strong>h most authors coming from a social exclusionangle <strong>and</strong> almost by defin<strong>it</strong>ion dissatisfied by the service <strong>banks</strong> give.In all countries examined the take-up of pol<strong>it</strong>ically m<strong>and</strong>ated basic oruniversal banking accounts has been slow, although most <strong>banks</strong> providethem because not to <strong>do</strong> so risks direct regulatory pressure on the pricingof basic banking services.* figures s<strong>how</strong>n for guarantee schemes are the amount of lending supported notthe guarantee amount9293


In the UK, the concept of the “Universal Bank” operating out of the postoffice(which would have been l<strong>it</strong>tle more than a next generationreinvention of the Post-Office Girobank set up in the 1960s <strong>and</strong> privatisedto one of the building society <strong>banks</strong> in the 1980s) failed to take root<strong>and</strong> appears to have been replaced by a range of agreements betweenPost-Office Counters <strong>and</strong> various <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> building societies allowingcustomers of those inst<strong>it</strong>utions to <strong>access</strong> their accounts through local postoffices. This approach was used actively to m<strong>it</strong>igate the impact of significantrural branch closures by Barclays <strong>and</strong> other <strong>banks</strong> in 2003 along w<strong>it</strong>h theplacing of more remote ATMs in non-bank retail outlets. The response tothis from consumer organisations, <strong>how</strong>ever, focused on the preference forelderly customers in particular for face-to-face contact, which transmutedthe perception of exclusion from geographical into age-based.The one dimension of exclusion where <strong>banks</strong> across the advanced industrialworld are taking a more pro-active approach is in the area of financiall<strong>it</strong>eracy discussed in Chapter 2. This has a relatively long history back tothe recessions of the 1980s when <strong>it</strong> became increasingly clear thateducating small-scale entrepreneurs in the need for business <strong>and</strong> marketplanning helped improve the qual<strong>it</strong>y of SME lending. The focus is nowmore on individuals, where there is a sense that lack of underst<strong>and</strong>ingof <strong>how</strong> finance works leads to false expectations <strong>and</strong> subsequentdisappointment w<strong>it</strong>h the more sophisticated investment-based <strong>and</strong>consumer cred<strong>it</strong> products that <strong>banks</strong> need to sell to customers if they areto improve customer prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y.The pos<strong>it</strong>ion on enterprise <strong>access</strong> is also more pro-active w<strong>it</strong>h most <strong>banks</strong>more than willing to participate in publicly funded or supported microlendingprogrammes provided that any imposed constraints on theirpricing properly reflect the extra cost of loan processing. This is helped bythe fact that in a low inflation, low interest rate world, the operationalcosts of raising retail depos<strong>it</strong>s rises relative to the wholesale market fundingcost at which most of these schemes operate. Moreover, as wholesalerates fall, the discount for qual<strong>it</strong>y that government funding implies risesin importance relative to the base wholesale funding cost. This makespublicly sponsored on-lending programmes more attractive but to be brutallyhonest about this process, <strong>it</strong> would not matter who the end-recipient was<strong>and</strong> participation is not really an indication of shared concern about theimportance of <strong>access</strong> for very small enterprises. This probably explainswhy overall such schemes tend to suffer from “mission creep” as bankersseek out those larger customers w<strong>it</strong>hin the target market that havethe larger borrowing needs over which to spread relatively fixed loanprocessing costs.94E. Banking sector responses to issues of <strong>access</strong>in developing economiesThe same CGAP [1998] note discussed in section 2 above gives insightsinto the administrative structures used by <strong>banks</strong> to carry out fairlyst<strong>and</strong>ard microfinance operations:■ Fully independent retail centres, affiliated to the bank but w<strong>it</strong>h theirown lending policies, staff, <strong>and</strong> information systems that report to thelarger bank (Banco del Desarrollo’s microfinance subsidiary in Chile,the Un<strong>it</strong> Desa of Bank Rakyat In<strong>do</strong>nesia, <strong>and</strong> the Social EnterpriseProgram of the Bank of Nova Scotia in Guyana).■ Lending through NGOs that, in turn, on-lend to micro-enterpriseclients (Banco Wiese in Peru).■ Semi-independent microfinance un<strong>it</strong>s lending directly <strong>and</strong>/or specialisedwin<strong>do</strong>ws in each bank branch, staffed w<strong>it</strong>h a microfinance cred<strong>it</strong> officer.Administrative <strong>and</strong> financial functions are integrated into the largerbank (Banco del Esta<strong>do</strong>, Chile; Banco Agrícola Comercial, El Salva<strong>do</strong>r;Banco del Pacífico, Ecua<strong>do</strong>r; Financiera Familiar, Paraguay; <strong>and</strong>Government Savings Bank / National Bank for Development, Thail<strong>and</strong>).■ Fully integrated operations, wherein small business cred<strong>it</strong> officers alsoh<strong>and</strong>le microenterprise clients. All administrative, personnel, <strong>and</strong> financialsystems are integrated (Caja de Ahorro y Créd<strong>it</strong>o Los Andes <strong>and</strong>BancoSol, Bolivia; Banco Caja Social, Colombia; Multi-cred<strong>it</strong> Bank,Panama; Tanzania Postal Bank; <strong>and</strong> Centenary Bank, Ug<strong>and</strong>a).Most of the commercial <strong>banks</strong> attending the USAID conference offeredmicro-loans through a separate win<strong>do</strong>w or through part of the branch officethat h<strong>and</strong>les only microfinance clients. This separation allowed both thestaff <strong>and</strong> clients to recognise the different terms between the trad<strong>it</strong>ionalcommercial banking services <strong>and</strong> microfinance services. The study suggestsa pos<strong>it</strong>ive correlation between the degree of independence of themicrofinance un<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong> the scale of the operation. Moreover, <strong>banks</strong> w<strong>it</strong>hspecialised independent microfinance un<strong>it</strong>s or subsidiaries found <strong>it</strong> easierto inst<strong>it</strong>ute microfinance lending policies, procedures, <strong>and</strong> metho<strong>do</strong>logies<strong>and</strong> avoid interference from the larger bank culture. Perhaps the mostdramatic example is Bank of Nova Scotia that operates a group-lendingprogramme in Guyana w<strong>it</strong>h loans mostly under US$300 under theumbrella of a large, sophisticated, foreign-owned commercial bank.95


One other interesting possibil<strong>it</strong>y highlighted by Morduch <strong>and</strong> Hayley[2002] is the co-operation between PRODEM in Bolivia <strong>and</strong> BancoSol.PRODEM sets up small-scale solidar<strong>it</strong>y-group model “<strong>banks</strong>” w<strong>it</strong>h targetaverage loan sizes of $300-400 <strong>and</strong> then sells these on to BancoSol whenthey become prof<strong>it</strong>able.Yaron [2004] <strong>and</strong> Yaron, Benjamin <strong>and</strong> Piprek [1997] provide a casestudy of achieving financial self-sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y based on BRI-UD bankin Java, In<strong>do</strong>nesia. This rural bank involves a model w<strong>it</strong>h the followingmain features:■ Market based charging for cred<strong>it</strong>.■ Active depos<strong>it</strong> mobilisation so that resource-dependence on the stateor on <strong>do</strong>nors is gradually phased out.■ Transfer of the benef<strong>it</strong>s of realistic interest rates on loans to depos<strong>it</strong>orsto further stimulate the sustained growth of depos<strong>it</strong> resources.Summary parameters s<strong>how</strong>ing the performance of the bank over the10 year period 1985 to 1995 are s<strong>how</strong>n in the table below:Table 11: BRI-UD bank – a ten-year progression1985 1990 1995Average annual Loan Volumes ($ million) 162 562 1178No of Outst<strong>and</strong>ing Loans (million) 1.0 1.9 2.9Average outst<strong>and</strong>ing loan amount ($) 162 296 51Average annual Depos<strong>it</strong> Volume ($ million) 49 685 2382No of Depos<strong>it</strong> Accounts (million) n/a 7.3 14.5Average depos<strong>it</strong> per saver ($) n/a 94 164Average Interest on loan portfolio 27.4% 51.5% 31.8%Average Interest paid on Depos<strong>it</strong>s 10.5% 11.3% 9.7%Nominal interest rate needed forFinancial Self-Sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y 36.2% 27.2% 17.5%Paulson <strong>and</strong> McAndrews [1998] also provide a case study of theimplementation w<strong>it</strong>hin one bank – St<strong>and</strong>ard Bank of South Africa – ofradical new ways of addressing an un-banked population. In 1993St<strong>and</strong>ard Bank set up E-Bank, w<strong>it</strong>h a simple <strong>savings</strong> product offeringcard-only <strong>access</strong> but supported by dedicated staff speaking a mix ofrelevant local languages <strong>and</strong> operating out of dedicated outlets to helpovercome problems of ill<strong>it</strong>eracy <strong>and</strong> concerns about secur<strong>it</strong>y in a highcrime environment. Three key modifications helped deliver this. First, theoutlets were designed around the ATMs’ own cash-secur<strong>it</strong>y features <strong>and</strong>because money was not being h<strong>and</strong>led outside the ATMs the physicalsecur<strong>it</strong>y of the outlet <strong>it</strong>self could be reduced. This allowed the outletsto be open to the street <strong>and</strong> much more approachable than trad<strong>it</strong>ionalSt<strong>and</strong>ard Bank branches. Second, each customer was issued w<strong>it</strong>h a“stop-card” that they themselves could use to block their account if theirATM <strong>access</strong> card was lost or compromised. Finally, the account offereda segmented “<strong>savings</strong> purse” that could only be <strong>access</strong>ed in personw<strong>it</strong>h ID-verification by one of the staff. The products were running offexisting systems <strong>and</strong> designed to cost-recover w<strong>it</strong>hout becoming toocostly, although there was never any attempt to become a low-costsupplier. The bank recru<strong>it</strong>ed 150,000 customers in <strong>it</strong>s first year buttransaction volumes were never as high as were needed to cover heavystart-up costs for the construction of the outlets <strong>and</strong> purchases of newATMs. This was resolved by the bank folding E-Bank back into <strong>it</strong>s mainbr<strong>and</strong> as E-Plan <strong>and</strong> Auto E-Bank, <strong>and</strong> then taking the opportun<strong>it</strong>y totransfer over low-income customers from other higher-cost services.F. Implications for future policy■■Clearly <strong>banks</strong> can be guided towards keeping <strong>access</strong>ibil<strong>it</strong>y on theirmanagement agenda by such instruments as the CRA in the Un<strong>it</strong>edStates <strong>and</strong> the Finance Sector Charter in South Africa. In some casesthis may even stimulate efforts to improve <strong>access</strong> (as in South Africa).A more unresolved question, <strong>how</strong>ever, is whether such regulatorypressure really has more leverage on bank behaviour than <strong>do</strong> concernsabout the public relations consequences for large <strong>banks</strong> of being seento cut back on <strong>access</strong>.Banks are also clearly keen to participate in publicly supported SMEfinancing <strong>and</strong> will even venture into qu<strong>it</strong>e small-scale cred<strong>it</strong>ing providedthey are not impeded from <strong>do</strong>ing so by clumsy regulation.9697


■ It is much less clear whether m<strong>and</strong>ating <strong>access</strong> ever really works –<strong>banks</strong> can create basic accounts but take-up is often poor <strong>and</strong> usageonce created can be poorer still.■ There would seem to be real opportun<strong>it</strong>ies, particularly in a developingcountry context, to stimulate significant expansion of bank-basedmicrofinance by pragmatic modifications of regulatory requirementsw<strong>it</strong>hout <strong>do</strong>ing anything to encourage undue risk-taking. An exampleof such pragmatism is the recent scaling back of the potential increasein the risk-weighting of SME lending as part of the negotiation ofBasel II.■ This greater involvement of <strong>banks</strong> in microfinance is almost certainlyv<strong>it</strong>al to building real financial self-sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y (<strong>and</strong> reduced relianceon <strong>do</strong>nors) for microfinance.5. THE ROLE OF SAVINGS BANKSA. OverviewThe issue of <strong>access</strong> is taken seriously by the proxim<strong>it</strong>y bank movement –<strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong>, co-operative <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> commun<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> worldwide.Access <strong>and</strong> exclusion are directly inferred in four of the paragraphs of theMadrid declaration of World Savings Banks Inst<strong>it</strong>ute <strong>and</strong> a Resolution onAccess to Finance was a<strong>do</strong>pted by <strong>it</strong>s membership in 2004. This chapter seeksto answer three key questions about the impact of that comm<strong>it</strong>ment:■■■Does the differing strength of the proxim<strong>it</strong>y bank movement inindividual countries or groups of similar countries explain the verywide spectrum of indicated performance regarding <strong>access</strong> worldwide?<strong>What</strong> is <strong>it</strong> that proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> <strong>do</strong> in terms of product offering <strong>and</strong>other services to customers <strong>and</strong> the commun<strong>it</strong>ies they are drawn from,that can make the difference in terms of broadening <strong>access</strong>? <strong>and</strong>;How <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> regulation <strong>and</strong> other public policy help or hinder this process?B. The importance of proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> to levels of <strong>access</strong>This topic is inextricably tied up w<strong>it</strong>h the long stream of debate onwhether proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> <strong>do</strong> actually deliver the social gains presumed ofthem at an acceptable cost in terms of distortions to compet<strong>it</strong>ion w<strong>it</strong>hinbanking systems as a whole.Regarding advanced industrial economies a paper by Berger, Hasan &Klapper [2003] for World Bank finds that a strong market share for smallprivate <strong>banks</strong>, provided they are efficiently run, has beneficial effects onoverall economic development but not particularly through the expectedchannel of strengthened SME development.9899


An obvious weakness of the study is that <strong>it</strong> is not clear that the underlyingdatabase 17 properly captures the work of socially-owned proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong>.Focusing more specifically on the social banking movement (i.e. publiclyowned<strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> mutually-owned <strong>banks</strong>), recent work by PA Consulting[2004] identified a negative impact of social ownership on overall bankingsystem prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y. Commentators took this further to suggest socialownership reduces the scope for overall banking system development.This, <strong>how</strong>ever, represents a very reduced form of the compet<strong>it</strong>ive processin a diversified banking system. No indication was given whether thisreduced prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y was a material constraint on cap<strong>it</strong>alisation of<strong>do</strong>mestic banking activ<strong>it</strong>ies or whether a strong compet<strong>it</strong>ive input fromsocially owned <strong>banks</strong> helped keep <strong>do</strong>wn prices, thereby exp<strong>and</strong>ing thevolume of intermediation <strong>and</strong> affordabil<strong>it</strong>y of <strong>access</strong>. Figure 12 belowcertainly suggests that <strong>it</strong> is not obviously proved that reduced prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>yin banking systems w<strong>it</strong>h a high element of social ownership reduces thecapac<strong>it</strong>y to meet <strong>do</strong>mestic banking requirements. Access in these bankingsystems is just as high as in supposedly more “compet<strong>it</strong>ive” markets w<strong>it</strong>ha lower social ownership of <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> higher prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y.Figure 12: Ownership 18 , prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y 19 <strong>and</strong> degree of <strong>access</strong> 20comparedPROFITABILITY2.40%2.00%1.60%1.20%0.80%0.40%0.0%0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70%Share of socially-owned <strong>banks</strong> in total assetsACCESS LEVELS120%100%80%60%40%20%0%0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70%Share of socially-owned <strong>banks</strong> in total assets17 Bureau van Dijk’s Bankscope database, which purports to capture at least 85% of eachcountry’s banking system by assets. Desp<strong>it</strong>e good coverage <strong>and</strong> minor reporting errors inthe individual reported un<strong>it</strong>s, Bhattacharya [2003] finds strong evidence of selectiv<strong>it</strong>y biasin BankScope data for India. A major source of the selectiv<strong>it</strong>y bias for India is the almosttotal omission of regional rural <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> some forms of foreign <strong>banks</strong> (branches are notcaptured nor are small subsidiaries). It is s<strong>how</strong>n that this selectiv<strong>it</strong>y bias affects estimatesof all summary statistical measures although desp<strong>it</strong>e these lim<strong>it</strong>ations, the paper s<strong>how</strong>sthat a few popularly used market concentration measures could be estimated accurately,provided the coverage ratio w<strong>it</strong>h respect to the size variable is known from alternativesources <strong>and</strong> is adequate (90% w<strong>it</strong>h respect to the size variable is found to be sufficient forapproximating k-bank concentration measures, providing accurate estimates could beobtained of the top k <strong>banks</strong> in the population).Sources: PA Consulting [2004] for prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> share of social-<strong>banks</strong>; Pesaresi <strong>and</strong>Pilley [2003] plus Caskey [2002] for <strong>access</strong> levels18 Ownership measured by share of socially-owned <strong>banks</strong> in total banking system assets.19 Prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y measured by gross return on assets.20 Access measured by proportion of adult population w<strong>it</strong>h personal current account, giroaccount or similar.100101


Aggregate analysis like this also misses the point about proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong>being the ultimate bulwark against geographic exclusion as national <strong>and</strong>international <strong>banks</strong> react to the pressures of globalisation by rationalisingbranch networks <strong>and</strong> customer lists. This has been a very real problem inGermany where M<strong>it</strong>telst<strong>and</strong> customers of many years st<strong>and</strong>ing have beentold by the large private <strong>banks</strong> that their business is no longer welcome.Here the PA Consulting report may have a point in that this could havebeen a reaction to very fine margins on regional SME banking but forcommentators to then question the right of those <strong>banks</strong> to exist in theircurrent form is a perverse conclusion to draw.Figure 13 below, again exposes the fallacy of the argument that more“compet<strong>it</strong>ive” markets w<strong>it</strong>h a lower social ownership <strong>and</strong> higher prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>yserve the SME sector better. Indeed the reverse appears to be true, w<strong>it</strong>hthe proportion of SMEs declaring a lack of <strong>access</strong> to finance as the mainconstraint on their business lower in the countries w<strong>it</strong>h a high degree ofsocial ownership.Figure 13: Ownership, prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> SME dissatisfactionw<strong>it</strong>h <strong>access</strong>PROFITABILITY2.40%2.00%1.60%1.20%0.80%0.40%0.0%0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70%Share of socially-owned <strong>banks</strong> in total assetsSources: PA Consulting [2004] for prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> share of social-<strong>banks</strong>; EIM [2004] for SMEdissatisfactionAs regards developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies the case is now clearly madethat a strong <strong>savings</strong> bank has a v<strong>it</strong>al part to play in helping an economymove towards full <strong>access</strong>. <strong>What</strong> is not yet clear, is at what stage ofeconomic <strong>and</strong> financial development <strong>do</strong> commercial <strong>banks</strong> start to offer<strong>mean</strong>ingful <strong>access</strong>. This will only start to be answered when the data puttogether for this study <strong>and</strong> further work being <strong>do</strong>ne on data sources onmicrofinance have been consistently integrated <strong>and</strong> then further integratedw<strong>it</strong>h data that World Bank is beginning to get from regulators of commercial<strong>banks</strong>. This is work underway <strong>and</strong> should yield results in 2006. The mainpolicy issues still to be addressed regarding <strong>access</strong> to finance by <strong>savings</strong><strong>banks</strong> in developing <strong>and</strong> emerging market economies are:■■SME DISSATISFACTION14%12%10%8%6%4%2%0%0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70%Share of socially-owned <strong>banks</strong> in total assetsHow the relative weight of <strong>savings</strong> bank branch networks <strong>and</strong> staffingcompared to that of other <strong>banks</strong> in each country affects presence <strong>and</strong><strong>access</strong>.The impact of structural form <strong>and</strong> ownership (particularly w<strong>it</strong>hin a PostOffice context) affects presence <strong>and</strong> <strong>access</strong>. If postal <strong>savings</strong> are toplay a <strong>mean</strong>ingful role in providing <strong>access</strong> this activ<strong>it</strong>y, they must beput onto a properly const<strong>it</strong>uted banking basis w<strong>it</strong>h ring-fencing ofcustomers’ depos<strong>it</strong>s <strong>and</strong> proper settlements systems <strong>and</strong> balance sheet<strong>and</strong> risk management processes. In many countries of the developingworld this is not the case <strong>and</strong> postal <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> rarely mobilisesignificant depos<strong>it</strong> volumes in such circumstances.102103


C. <strong>What</strong> proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> <strong>do</strong> to improve individual <strong>access</strong>1. Comm<strong>it</strong>ment in principleMost <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> will have in their founding statutes or missionstatement a comm<strong>it</strong>ment to offer universal <strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> many privatecommun<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> will seek to offer <strong>access</strong> to those potential customersnot offered <strong>mean</strong>ingful <strong>access</strong> by larger national <strong>banks</strong>. A selection ofexamples from around the world of this high level comm<strong>it</strong>ment are:■■■■■the battle against financial <strong>and</strong> bank exclusion const<strong>it</strong>utes a historicvocation <strong>and</strong> more than that [<strong>it</strong>] is wr<strong>it</strong>ten into the [Savings Bank]law of 25 June 1999.Caisse d’Epargne, FranceAccording to <strong>it</strong>s mission as a state-owned bank, BancoEsta<strong>do</strong> has akey role providing <strong>access</strong> to finance [for] new social <strong>and</strong> economicactors.Banco Esta<strong>do</strong>, ChileUnder Republic Act 7354 creating the Philippine Postal Corporation<strong>and</strong> providing for the re-opening of the old Postal Savings Bank,PostalBank is m<strong>and</strong>ated to establish presence in the countrysidewhich has not fully enjoyed the benef<strong>it</strong>s of banking <strong>and</strong> financialservices. Establishing PostalBank branches in municipal<strong>it</strong>ies untouchedby the banking system will help tap underutilized Local GovernmentUn<strong>it</strong> (LGU) funds <strong>and</strong> pool small <strong>savings</strong> to provide local financing toSMEs <strong>and</strong> Micro-enterprises, NGOs, cooperatives, OFW dependents<strong>and</strong> other groups.Philippine Postal Savings Bank, Inc, PhilippinesSSB have the most extensive network, <strong>and</strong> we are proud to serveall people in Spain, especially those w<strong>it</strong>h a lower economic level.One of our main objectives is to avoid financial exclusion.Spanish Savings Banks, SpainOur core m<strong>and</strong>ate is to mobilise <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> inculcate a <strong>savings</strong>culture among Kenyans.Kenya Post Office Savings Banks, Kenya■great prior<strong>it</strong>y has been given to the “banca popular” strategy,through which <strong>access</strong> to financial services is being provided to mostMexicans in a secure way, w<strong>it</strong>h the aim of promoting <strong>and</strong>facil<strong>it</strong>ating economic <strong>and</strong> social development.Bansefi, MexicoThese comm<strong>it</strong>ments are not only <strong>do</strong>mestic. Through subsidiaryfoundations both the German <strong>and</strong> Spanish <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> are veryactive in international co-operation w<strong>it</strong>h developing country proxim<strong>it</strong>y<strong>banks</strong> world-wide. Other advanced industrial economy <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong>engage in similar activ<strong>it</strong>ies under the WSBI <strong>and</strong> <strong>it</strong>s sister organisation,ESBG, the European Savings Banks Group.2. Avoiding exclusion by design <strong>and</strong> cond<strong>it</strong>ionOne of the biggest tangible comm<strong>it</strong>ments a <strong>savings</strong> bank can make tomaintaining <strong>access</strong> for vulnerable groups is to retain a basic <strong>savings</strong>passbook system w<strong>it</strong>h procedures to allow this to be <strong>access</strong>ed at anyoutlet. This is specifically mentioned by Caisse d’Epargne, France as aproduct of fundamental importance to “fragile groups” but is commonamong the <strong>savings</strong> bank movements around the world. This is not tosay that <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> are wedded to old technology – in the samesubmission Caisse d’Epargne, France describe their VISA Electron cardprogramme as a budget management tool for the same fragile groups<strong>and</strong> proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> in South Africa are following exactly the samestrategy (Teba Bank – ACard).Savings <strong>banks</strong> can also be significant distributors of governmentbackedspecial <strong>savings</strong> schemes for small investors. An example of thisis in India where the National Savings Inst<strong>it</strong>ute (NSI) (an office of theMinistry of Finance) has nine specialist “Small Savings Programmes”designed to cater to the needs of all sections of small savers - seniorc<strong>it</strong>izens, housewives, farmers, wage earners, students, etc. They carryan implic<strong>it</strong> sovereign guarantee <strong>and</strong> are thus a safe avenue forinvestment by all c<strong>it</strong>izens. Tax concessions <strong>and</strong> attractive return oninvestment are also some of the measures to target the customers.104105


Box 6: Turning income into <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> cred<strong>it</strong> opportun<strong>it</strong>ies –Brazil, Mexico & SpainEven the poor have income, albe<strong>it</strong> often irregular <strong>and</strong> unreliable.The mass-middle market in many developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economiesmay even have regular income but at too low levels to carry the fullcharges of a commercial bank current account. So any product orcombination of products that captures that flow of income w<strong>it</strong>houtrestricting the abil<strong>it</strong>y to spend <strong>it</strong> has enormous potential to improve<strong>access</strong>. Below are three examples of <strong>how</strong> <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> in Brazil,Mexico <strong>and</strong> Spain are <strong>do</strong>ing just that.Caixa Economica Federal of Brazil’s card based CAIXA AQUI accountis built around simplified application procedures <strong>and</strong> <strong>access</strong> throughpoint-of-sale terminals at correspondents such as the State Lottery.This dramatically extends Caixa’s outreach – adding 12000 <strong>access</strong>points to the <strong>banks</strong> main network of 2200 offices – <strong>and</strong> Caixa Aqu<strong>it</strong>ranslates as “Caixa is present”. Three million accounts (over 10% ofall Caixa accounts) have been opened in a period of just two years.The accounts take regular payments of social benef<strong>it</strong>s such aspensions but also have scope to take cash depos<strong>it</strong>s. The accountopening includes a pre-agreement to provide cred<strong>it</strong> <strong>and</strong> after ninetydays of account use, provided all is in order <strong>and</strong> cadastral checksidentify no existing defaults the bank automatically sends thecustomer a contract to sign if they want to take an in<strong>it</strong>ial cred<strong>it</strong> of upto R$ 200 (equal to just under US$ 70) for a period of four monthsat an interest cost of 2% per month. After this period, scoring of aclient’s actual cred<strong>it</strong> performance <strong>and</strong> ongoing account use allows<strong>access</strong> to larger amounts for longer periods (potentially up to a year).In parallel w<strong>it</strong>h this Caixa launched E-ACCOUNT CAIXA for Braziliansworking abroad who want to send rem<strong>it</strong>tances home direct from ahost-country cred<strong>it</strong> card. The account is available in 50 countries <strong>and</strong>the cost of a typical transfer is just 2_% compared to 8~15% typicalof more trad<strong>it</strong>ional channels. These rem<strong>it</strong>tances can feed Aquiaccounts of relatives <strong>and</strong> a second stage of the international e-banking project will allow migrant workers in the US to <strong>access</strong> theirown Aqui accounts directly through Caixa Aqui terminals in branchesof a Portuguese bank present there.BANSEFI of Mexico, is the successor to that country’s state <strong>savings</strong>bank that has been restructured to become in add<strong>it</strong>ion theapex organisation for a reformed popular <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> cred<strong>it</strong>movement. As local Cajas de Ahorro come into compliance w<strong>it</strong>hthe new regulatory regime for hem, they have <strong>access</strong> to technicalassistance, new technology, accounting support <strong>and</strong> a commonbr<strong>and</strong> L@Red de la Gente. They also get <strong>access</strong> to Bansefi’s socialbenef<strong>it</strong>s <strong>and</strong> rem<strong>it</strong>tances distribution capac<strong>it</strong>y. This allows them tooffer depos<strong>it</strong> products that can receive social benef<strong>it</strong>s orrem<strong>it</strong>tances channelled through Bansefi, which has negotiated anumber of contracts w<strong>it</strong>h government <strong>and</strong> <strong>banks</strong> abroad toreceive <strong>and</strong> distribute such money. Bansefi research s<strong>how</strong>s thatw<strong>it</strong>hin three to four cycles of a client receiving such inflows, theiraccount then typically starts to be used for voluntary depos<strong>it</strong>s of cash.Because Bansefi also manages pre-borrowing <strong>savings</strong> accounts fora number of low cost loan schemes <strong>it</strong> is also able to offer migrantworkers the abil<strong>it</strong>y to qualify abroad for cheap housing finance fore<strong>it</strong>her themselves or their relatives.CECA – the Spanish Confederation of Savings Banks – hasnegotiated a 16 bilateral agreements w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> in12 different countries to distribute rem<strong>it</strong>tances at around halfthe normal cost of more trad<strong>it</strong>ional channels. This in<strong>it</strong>ial phasewill cover fully three quarters of the foreign c<strong>it</strong>izens who live inSpain <strong>and</strong> will be exp<strong>and</strong>ed later. It has the <strong>do</strong>uble benef<strong>it</strong> ofproviding affordable <strong>access</strong> not only in the home country but also<strong>access</strong> for the migrant worker in Spain.One common product feature often talked about as a major barrier to<strong>access</strong> is the minimum balance required by some <strong>banks</strong> to maintain anaccount. As already noted, <strong>it</strong> is unlikely that this is a particular problemfor <strong>access</strong>ing <strong>savings</strong> bank accounts – if <strong>it</strong> were, average depos<strong>it</strong>balances at <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> would be higher than at other <strong>do</strong>ublebottom-line inst<strong>it</strong>utions. This is just not the case.106107


Moreover, Table 12 below s<strong>how</strong>s that <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> can <strong>and</strong> <strong>do</strong> workw<strong>it</strong>h average balances that are same low proportion of per-cap<strong>it</strong>a GDPin the poorest 20% of countries as they work w<strong>it</strong>h in the richest 20%.Table 12: Average depos<strong>it</strong> balances by country income groupMedian depos<strong>it</strong> balance- as a percentagein Euroof per cap<strong>it</strong>a GDPIncome b<strong>and</strong> (in Euro per annum)Below 400 56 24%400~1000 163 27%1000~3000 315 16%3000~15000 143 3%Over 15000 6,325 25%Anec<strong>do</strong>tal evidence suggests that most <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> still acceptbasic <strong>savings</strong> accounts w<strong>it</strong>h flexible <strong>access</strong> both for depos<strong>it</strong>ing <strong>and</strong>w<strong>it</strong>hdrawal <strong>and</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h very low or zero minimum required balances(see WSBI [2004], which s<strong>how</strong>s minimum required balances for a numberof African postal <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> equal to roughly 2~3% of per cap<strong>it</strong>a GDP<strong>and</strong> less than half this for a number of Southern American <strong>savings</strong><strong>banks</strong>). Far more serious is the issue of cost <strong>and</strong> account charges.3. Avoiding exclusion by maintaining affordabil<strong>it</strong>yThere are two ways of looking at this <strong>and</strong> both are attempted hereafter.Unfortunately the data is not uniform across countries <strong>and</strong> inst<strong>it</strong>utions.This (along w<strong>it</strong>h collection of data on loan account numbers) is an areathat would repay further effort by WSBI <strong>and</strong> <strong>it</strong>s members.The first step is to look at the ratio of operating costs to total assets at<strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> compare these to similar ratios for MFIs. This suggeststhat the largest <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> operate at qu<strong>it</strong>e low cost ratios (annualoperating costs equal to 1~4% total assets) <strong>and</strong> even at the top-en<strong>do</strong>f the normal range of <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong>’ cost ratios, they are still muchlower than similarly calculated ratios at microfinance inst<strong>it</strong>utions(most MFIs in the CGAP MiX-MBB database have cost ratios in the20~30% range).Figure 14: Savings bank cost to asset ratios by regionCosts as percent total assets15%12%9%6%3%0%Typical range, excluding highest <strong>and</strong> lowest cost<strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> in regionS & E AsiaAverage for all <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> in regionEurope &C AsiaC & S AmericaMid-East &AfricaThe reason that this cost ratio matters, is that <strong>it</strong> determines the wedgebetween what an inst<strong>it</strong>ution can afford to pay depos<strong>it</strong>ors for <strong>savings</strong>mobilised <strong>and</strong> what <strong>it</strong> must extract by way of interest income earned<strong>and</strong> fees/commissions received. The wedge is high for MFIs <strong>and</strong> this iswhy they are invariably seen as a high-cost source of cred<strong>it</strong> whencompared to other formal sources of finance. Because the ratio for<strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> is low, even for the <strong>banks</strong> <strong>do</strong>ing the most cred<strong>it</strong>ing,these <strong>banks</strong> have the possibil<strong>it</strong>y of becoming relatively low-costproviders of small-scale finance w<strong>it</strong>hout having to subsidise cred<strong>it</strong>orsat the expense of depos<strong>it</strong>ors.At the heart of this phenomenon is the very much higher productiv<strong>it</strong>ytypical of <strong>savings</strong> bank staff than microfinance specialists. The formerwill be h<strong>and</strong>ling roughly 900 accounts each; the latter perhaps 150.Of course some of the 900 accounts will be inactive but not the 85%or so needed to bring the two numbers into line w<strong>it</strong>h each other. Evenif this were to be the case, all the inactive accounts will still be creatingcontinuously some net interest margin to help cover the costs ofaccounts that happen to be incurring transaction costs at any onepoint in time. There is also a common misconception that <strong>savings</strong>accounts must be easier to service than loan accounts but this isnot necessarily so. No one would dispute that the origination ofgood qual<strong>it</strong>y loans takes longer than opening new depos<strong>it</strong> products.108109


Once up <strong>and</strong> running, <strong>how</strong>ever, a loan account creates one, maybe twotransactions per month. A typical <strong>savings</strong> bank account will create exactlythe same turnover if not more <strong>and</strong> the timing of that turnover is if anythingless under the control of the bank than the timing of loan activ<strong>it</strong>y.Figure 15: Savings bank staff productiv<strong>it</strong>yNumber of <strong>banks</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h data12Table 13: Accounts h<strong>and</strong>led per <strong>savings</strong> bank employee,by location of outletProductiv<strong>it</strong>y greater Major c<strong>it</strong>y branches Outside major c<strong>it</strong>iesin major c<strong>it</strong>iesSweden 900 620Vietnam 250 149Comores 918 130Zimbabwe 5906 347110864200~500All members w<strong>it</strong>h a/c numbers dataNon-postal members only500~1000 1000~1500 1500~2000 2000~2500 2500~3000 over 3000Productiv<strong>it</strong>y b<strong>and</strong> - number of accounts per employeeProductiv<strong>it</strong>y greater Major c<strong>it</strong>y branches Outside major c<strong>it</strong>iesin major c<strong>it</strong>iesAustria 340 407Bulgaria 1304 1774Hungary 5024 6831Colombia (x2) 443 822Dom. Rep. 1008 1221Iran 348 358Ethiopia 89 109Table 13 analyses a sub-set of the data on staff productiv<strong>it</strong>y – base<strong>do</strong>n those members for which WSBI has data on account numbers bytype of outlet (national/regional cap<strong>it</strong>als versus outside major urbanareas). This s<strong>how</strong>s a three-to-two ratio between the number of <strong>savings</strong><strong>banks</strong> where staff h<strong>and</strong>le more accounts per head outside the majorurban areas than inside <strong>and</strong> the number of <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> wherethe reverse is true. This confirms more than ten years of consultingexperience for one of the authors – <strong>savings</strong> banking is a scaleablebusiness right <strong>do</strong>wn to the smallest scale rural outlet.The final stage in this analysis is to look at the price that <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong>actually charge customers for the use of their accounts. Here muchmore data is needed but the table below s<strong>how</strong>s the tariff structure fora number of passbook-based <strong>and</strong> card accounts at a mix of postal <strong>and</strong>non-postal WSBI members drawn from around the world.110111


Table 14: Sample calculations of cost of use for a passbookCentral & Southern Selected African South & EastAmerica Postal Saving Banks AsiaBanca Caixa Caisse Postbank Bank PostalCaja Econ. d’Epargne Simpanan SavingsSocial, Federal, Nasional ServiceColombia Brazil Senegal Botswana Malaysia VietnamTARIFF FOR PASSBOOKFixed monthly fee none none none €0.36 €0.20 noneManual cred<strong>it</strong> free free free free free freeManual deb<strong>it</strong> free €1.05 free free free freePASSBOOK USAGEIncome cred<strong>it</strong>ed per month €66.67 €100 €25 €167 €150 €17.5Manual cred<strong>it</strong> per month 1 1 1 1 1 1Manual deb<strong>it</strong> per month 2 2 2 2 2 2Cost per year €0 €26 €0 €4 €2 €0or % of average balance 0% 3.13% 0% 0.05% 1.98% 0%or % of assumed income 0% 2.10% 0% 0% 0.13% 0%TARIFF FOR CARD ACCOUNTFixed monthly fee €2.03 €1.15 €0.30ATM <strong>access</strong> €0.17 free n/aManual cred<strong>it</strong> free free freeManual deb<strong>it</strong> free €1.05 freeCARD ACCOUNT USAGEIncome cred<strong>it</strong>ed per month €133.33 €200 €300ATM <strong>access</strong> per week 1 1 1Manual cred<strong>it</strong> per month 1 1 1Manual deb<strong>it</strong> per month - - -Cost per year €33 €20 €4or % of average balance 4.12% 2.50% 2.98%or % of assumed income 2.08% 0.84% 0.10%Underlying these calculations are common assumptions that a passbookcustomer depos<strong>it</strong>s money once a month <strong>and</strong> w<strong>it</strong>hdraws cash twice amonth, <strong>and</strong> the amount passing through the account each month isthe equivalent half of per cap<strong>it</strong>a monthly GDP. For the card accountholder, the assumption is that salary is cred<strong>it</strong>ed once a month, an ATMw<strong>it</strong>hdrawal is made once a week <strong>and</strong> over-the-counter depos<strong>it</strong>s once amonth but manual w<strong>it</strong>hdrawals only every second month. The amountpassing through the account is assumed to equal per cap<strong>it</strong>a monthly GDP.The results of this very lim<strong>it</strong>ed snapshot are interesting – very basic <strong>savings</strong>accounts in many cases are provided effectively free of charge <strong>and</strong>even where charges are made can still be used to support day-to-daytransaction needs at affordable costs (roughly 2% to 3% of the averagebalances). More technological solutions are higher cost (2~4% ofaverage balances) probably because the technology has to be boughtin at world prices). These results need verifying, <strong>how</strong>ever, using amuch wider data sample. They also need benchmarking againstcommercial bank tariffs.4. Avoiding exclusion by maintaining physical <strong>access</strong>The other big tangible comm<strong>it</strong>ment a <strong>savings</strong> bank can make tomaintaining <strong>access</strong> is to maintain broad branch network cover. In countriesas diverse as Chile <strong>and</strong> Kenya the <strong>savings</strong> bank branch network willaccount for half the total outlets in the whole banking system <strong>and</strong>in many districts <strong>it</strong> will be the only <strong>access</strong> point for formal bankingservices.This is not just a developing country phenomenon – the members ofthe European Savings Bank Group account for very nearly 30% of allbanking system outlets in the EU-15 countries (ESBG [2003]). For allbut four exceptions, ESBG members’ branch networks are e<strong>it</strong>hergrowing faster than the rest of their home banking system or reducingmore slowly. Moreover ESBG members’ share of total non-bank depos<strong>it</strong>sin EU-15 banking systems is five percentage points lower than thereshare of branch outlets, pointing to a more mass-market pos<strong>it</strong>ioning.This is true on a country-by-country basis in all but three cases.Often <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> will stay in geographical areas <strong>and</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h marketsegments ab<strong>and</strong>oned by commercial <strong>banks</strong>. Research by the German<strong>savings</strong> bank movement (DSGV [2005]) s<strong>how</strong>s that 31 regions inGermany, accounting for 13% of national GDP, have no large privatebank representation at all <strong>and</strong> their only banking presence comes frome<strong>it</strong>her the <strong>savings</strong> or co-op banking movement. The divergence isparticularly marked when comparing across the old East/West divide,where for both zones the head of population per branch lies in the5~6000 range, whereas the equivalent figure for the large private <strong>banks</strong>is nearly 50,000 in the new Eastern L<strong>and</strong>er compared to 35,000 forthe Western L<strong>and</strong>er. Another particularly striking case is the Spanish<strong>savings</strong> bank movement, which has been opening branches while other<strong>banks</strong> in Spain have been reducing their networks. The movement’sdepos<strong>it</strong> market share had as a result risen above 50% by 2004.112113


In a qual<strong>it</strong>ative sense also the Spanish <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> are maintaininggreater reach, having more branches than the rest of the bankingsystem in the more rural less densely populated regions of Spain.In 13% of Spanish towns, most of them in depressed economic areas,a CECA member is the only bank. This deep reach almost certainlyexplains why <strong>access</strong> in Spain is so much higher than in other SouthernEuropean countries.5. Combating self- exclusionIn many developing countries proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> will be the only <strong>banks</strong>capable of dealing w<strong>it</strong>h the ill<strong>it</strong>erate poor who nevertheless manageto maintain some form of employment in the formal economy.In advanced industrial countries the issues are different but financialill<strong>it</strong>eracy is a real problem. Caisse d’Epargne, France has run aprogramme of financial education for more than 40 years now called“Finances & Pédagogie”. This uses seminars, booklets <strong>and</strong> newslettersto provide people w<strong>it</strong>h a general knowledge of Economy <strong>and</strong> Financeas well as practical information on <strong>how</strong> to manage their finances.It has specific elements aimed at “at people in precarious s<strong>it</strong>uationswho face an uncertain future (people in debt, unemployed.)…countering the economic dis-insertion of such people, often prior tobanking exclusion <strong>and</strong> the break<strong>do</strong>wn of social ties”. The programmeis available to anyone, not just clients of the bank. In Germany, a similarin<strong>it</strong>iative "Geld und Haushalt", run by DSGV, the German SavingsBanks Association, builds on 30 years co-operation between theSavings Banks School Service <strong>and</strong> German educationalists developingcomprehensive learning projects. Young people are introduced to theconcept of economics via a readily <strong>access</strong>ible <strong>and</strong> practice-orientedapproach that teaches them to h<strong>and</strong>le their finances sensibly <strong>and</strong>responsibly. One element of this work – “Planspiel Börse”, a stockexchange investment simulation game for secondary school students– is now shared by <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> in seven European countries.D. <strong>What</strong> proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> <strong>do</strong> specifically to improveenterprise <strong>access</strong>Savings <strong>banks</strong> are active partners in SME promotion. At a pan-Europeanlevel ESBG inputs directly into European Commission policy consultationsin this area but just as important are the local partnerships betweenindividual <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> local government in<strong>it</strong>iatives to promoteenterprise. This interest reflects the <strong>do</strong>minance of SME business in <strong>savings</strong>bank business portfolios but <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> across Europe provide morethan just lending support <strong>and</strong> payments services to SMEs <strong>and</strong> a numberrun special microfinance schemes as summarised in Box 7.Savings <strong>banks</strong> across the developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies of theworld are also very active in the arena of microfinance. Indeed, of the74 WSBI members in developing <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economies more than halfreported at the end of 2002 that they provided some form of microcred<strong>it</strong>.Since then, WSBI has been engaged in a comparative exercise <strong>do</strong>cumentingtheir experience w<strong>it</strong>h microfinance (WSBI [2004]). This includes six casesstudies from Africa, Asia <strong>and</strong> Latin America, three of which are brieflysummarised below:■Government Savings Bank of Thail<strong>and</strong>, has two major microfinanceprogrammes. The “Peoples Bank” project combines <strong>savings</strong> mobilisation<strong>and</strong> educational training for entrepreneurs w<strong>it</strong>h microcred<strong>it</strong>ing at aflat 1% per month rate of interest <strong>and</strong> loans of up to $750 for firsttimeborrowers <strong>and</strong> $1,250 for subsequent borrowing. €400 millionhad been disbursed by 2004 <strong>and</strong> almost a million loan applications peryear are being processed w<strong>it</strong>h more than a 90% approval rating <strong>and</strong>only a 3.5% delinquency. The “Village Fund” takes grant money fromthe Government of Thail<strong>and</strong> to pump-prime micro-cred<strong>it</strong>ing at 1.75%above current fixed depos<strong>it</strong> rates <strong>and</strong> has generated almost €4 billionof lending to 11 million villagers, off the back of a €1.6 billion grant<strong>and</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h only a 6% delinquency rate.114115


■■Banco Esta<strong>do</strong> de Chile runs a micro-enterprise programme that is anational leader w<strong>it</strong>h over 40% of the market. In 2003 <strong>it</strong> served 90,000micro-business people; about one third of them achieved <strong>access</strong> to afinancial inst<strong>it</strong>ution for the first time. This programme is servicedthrough 91 specialised platforms throughout the country <strong>and</strong> has arecovery rate of 99% of loans. Other important factors are that half ofcustomers are women <strong>and</strong> more than 90% of cred<strong>it</strong>s are processedw<strong>it</strong>hout guarantees. Banco Esta<strong>do</strong> also operates the Chilean statesmall business guarantee fund (FOGAPE), which has become animportant instrument to enhance <strong>access</strong> to finance. The number ofannual operations has nearly tripled in the past three years to reach30,000 in 2003 of which 70% are carried out in regions.Tanzania Postal Bank set up a micro-cred<strong>it</strong> scheme for microentrepreneurs<strong>and</strong> low-income households both in rural <strong>and</strong> urbanareas. This started in 2001 on a pilot basis in one district but has sincebeen rolled out to other locations. Only group-based micro-cred<strong>it</strong>s havebeen extended typically to groups of five, who can borrow between$50 <strong>and</strong> $600 at 2.5% per month for six to twelve months. To reduceadministrative burdens groups are clustered. By 31 December 2002,the total value of disbursed micro-loans stood at US$1.9 millionextended to 4,235 clients (80% female) in 676 groups out of whom41 had fully liquidated their first round loans. W<strong>it</strong>hin the micro-cred<strong>it</strong>scheme a special facil<strong>it</strong>y exists to provide seasonal agricultural finance<strong>and</strong> a parallel scheme for payroll-based lending to employed workershad disbursed similar volumes to the micro-cred<strong>it</strong> scheme.E. Policy as <strong>it</strong> affects proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> effortsto improve <strong>access</strong>The pressures that are coming from increasing globalisation of regulation<strong>and</strong> the impact of compet<strong>it</strong>ion policy were a major str<strong>and</strong> in the WSBIMadrid declaration. There is clearly an element here of non-joined-up publicpolicy w<strong>it</strong>h (a) the bank regulatory framework increasingly focused onrisk-adjusted prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> cap<strong>it</strong>alisation, (b) compet<strong>it</strong>ion policy focuse<strong>do</strong>n controlling state-aid <strong>and</strong> (c) wider economic strategy (e.g. the EuropeanUnion’s Lisbon agenda) focused on support for the sort of small <strong>and</strong>medium enterprise not well provided for by global banking groups.Box 7: Selected member in<strong>it</strong>iatives to <strong>foster</strong> microenterprisein advanced economiesMicrofinance is a discipline that has been designed <strong>and</strong> tested in adeveloping <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>it</strong>ion economy context but has since spread toadvanced industrial economies. As a banking system develops <strong>it</strong> hasto become <strong>access</strong>ible to the vast bulk of the individuals <strong>and</strong>enterprises that make up the economy <strong>it</strong> supports. But, there arealways people in those economies who for some reason or other –often educational, social or ethnographical – <strong>do</strong> not participate fullyin the formal structures of even the society to which they notionallybelong let alone <strong>it</strong>s economic structures 21 . Savings <strong>banks</strong> typically actin one of four ways to address these excluded groups:Sparkassen-Finanzgruppe in Germany is the major provider offinancial services to small <strong>and</strong> medium sized enterprises. As universal<strong>banks</strong> the <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> supply the whole range of financial servicesto corporate customers <strong>and</strong> overall market share in corporate financeon average exceeds 40%. As a rule the group can claim that thesmaller the companies the higher the market share they have. In lendingto enterprises w<strong>it</strong>h an annual turnover of up to €1/2 million the marketshare reaches 70%. Among the small <strong>and</strong> medium sized enterprisesin general, three quarters have some sort of relationship w<strong>it</strong>h a<strong>savings</strong> bank <strong>and</strong> 60% have the <strong>savings</strong> bank as their main bank.More than half of business start ups are financed by the group.Its Start-up Compet<strong>it</strong>ion <strong>and</strong> Deutscher Gründerpreis for newcompanies attract around 20,000 potential entrepreneurs a year <strong>and</strong>the group has equ<strong>it</strong>y shares in half of all German innovation <strong>and</strong>technology centres. In add<strong>it</strong>ion to <strong>it</strong>s own activ<strong>it</strong>ies the Sparkassen-Finanzgruppe participates in government supported schemes toprovide small scale loans to microenterprises. For example in 2004<strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> L<strong>and</strong>esbanken had a market share of 56% in theKfW-programmes "StartGeld" <strong>and</strong> "Mikrodarlehen".21 WSBI [2004] describes these forces of exclusion in more detail.116117


LloydsTSB in the UK, is active in the market for <strong>access</strong>ible enterprisefinance through making contributions of cap<strong>it</strong>al to specialist statesupportedmicroinvestment funds <strong>and</strong> also acting as an agent of thegovernment sponsored Small Business Guarantee Fund.Caisses d’Epargne in France runs a specialist programme – PELS orProjets d’économie locale et sociale – that provides some financedirectly to microentrepreneurs (about 55% of total disbursements)<strong>and</strong> the rest through local organisations that sponsor microenterprise.Since <strong>it</strong>s inception in 2001 some €50 million has been disbursed.Average loan size is in the region of €5000, w<strong>it</strong>h more than 6000microentrepreneurs provided w<strong>it</strong>h funding. Research indicates some5000 permanent jobs have been created, many for people previouslyon state assistance who would otherwise have no financing options.Members of the Spanish Savings Banks movement (Confederatedin CECA) operate a hybrid of these two approaches. Nine membersare working w<strong>it</strong>h a government run organisation (ICO) working w<strong>it</strong>hNGOs to identify socially worthwhile microcred<strong>it</strong> opportun<strong>it</strong>ies.In parallel, five of the <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> themselves run their ownmicrocred<strong>it</strong> operations on strictly financial <strong>and</strong> economic cr<strong>it</strong>eria.These are e<strong>it</strong>her guaranteed by the <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong>’ own socialfoundations or sometimes run through them. Some €16 million hasbeen disbursed to some 1700 borrowers.In all four models, strong links are built between <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong>non-banking organisations active in the field. Examples are Caissesd’Epargne in France co-operating w<strong>it</strong>h ADIE <strong>and</strong> Lloyds TSB in the UKco-operating w<strong>it</strong>h The Prince’s Trust. In add<strong>it</strong>ion to this most <strong>savings</strong><strong>banks</strong> will have contact w<strong>it</strong>h some sort of “business angels” networkthat allows them to put new microentrepreneurs in touch w<strong>it</strong>h moreexperienced business professionals.This is as much an issue in developing countries as advanced industrialeconomies. Specific examples from developing countries are:■■■Money laundering <strong>and</strong> anti-terrorism regulations in South Africa thatmake rem<strong>it</strong>tance transfers for migrant workers very difficult to process(echoed by Banco Caja Social in Colombia).The general regulatory burden (quoted by <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> in Chile, Iran,<strong>and</strong> Macau).GMF – a tax on transactions – that holds up payments systemdevelopment in Colombia.In this most of the <strong>savings</strong> <strong>banks</strong> are not seeking special favours (althoughsome <strong>do</strong> ask for tax subsidies to promote household saving) but areechoing the CGAP recommendations to government on <strong>foster</strong>ing moreeffective bank involvement in microfinance.The two main issues in advanced industrial economies are:■■How far should consolidation processes in Continental Europe go?Is there a conflict between compet<strong>it</strong>ion policy <strong>and</strong> the need for outreachto small <strong>and</strong> medium enterprises? All this is part of the wider debateon the role of socially-owned <strong>banks</strong> in developed banking systems.For commercial proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong> in the UK <strong>and</strong> US, the conflictbetween the design of government outreach programmes (CRA, basicbank accounts, etc) <strong>and</strong> the need to minimise un<strong>it</strong> operational costs ifsuch programmes are ever to work effectively.118119


6. A BRIEF POLICY AGENDAEMERGING FROMTHE ANALYSISBy synthesising the l<strong>it</strong>erature in Chapter 2 on the problems w<strong>it</strong>h <strong>access</strong>,w<strong>it</strong>h the difficulties in measuring different levels of <strong>access</strong> as discussedin Chapter 3 <strong>and</strong> the selected policy experiences laid out in Chapter 4, anumber of overarching themes emerge from this study. The main onesare as follows:■ The performance of banking systems cannot be understood in isolationfrom the pol<strong>it</strong>ical economy w<strong>it</strong>hin which they operate – government,especially in the richer economies, will <strong>do</strong> more to improve <strong>access</strong> byimproving the foundations of civil society than by trying to m<strong>and</strong>ate<strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> interfere w<strong>it</strong>h product design.■ If <strong>access</strong> is an important issue then <strong>it</strong> has to be measured better thanhas been possible here. That <strong>mean</strong>s collecting data on <strong>how</strong> manyaccounts have been opened in a country <strong>and</strong> who is opening them.Data from <strong>banks</strong> needs to be augmented by survey data to identify<strong>how</strong> many people have <strong>access</strong> to accounts <strong>and</strong> <strong>how</strong> many use them.■ Until <strong>access</strong> can be measured properly the cost-benef<strong>it</strong> case for <strong>banks</strong>trying to improve <strong>access</strong> is hard to make. The benef<strong>it</strong>s to government<strong>and</strong> international agencies from improved <strong>access</strong> may be greater thanthe net benef<strong>it</strong>s to <strong>banks</strong>. Att<strong>it</strong>udes to social banking <strong>and</strong> the elementof cross-subsidisation intrinsic to <strong>it</strong> need, therefore, to be adjustedaccordingly.■ If governments have good reasons for wanting to improve <strong>access</strong> thenregulation must take account of the pragmatic real<strong>it</strong>ies that face <strong>banks</strong>in reaching out to poorer commun<strong>it</strong>ies. This <strong>mean</strong>s tailoring physicalsecur<strong>it</strong>y, money-laundering, <strong>and</strong> loan provisioning requirements toreflect the challenges of <strong>do</strong>ing business in those commun<strong>it</strong>ies. This hasalready been <strong>do</strong>ne regarding risk-weighting SME lending for cap<strong>it</strong>aladequacy purposes; why can <strong>it</strong> not be <strong>do</strong>ne for, say, the impact ofanti-money laundering legislation on small-scale rem<strong>it</strong>tances by poorermigrant workers?■■Similarly if governments have reasons for wanting to improve <strong>access</strong>then their own actions must reinforce the link between being part ofa society <strong>and</strong> transacting day-to-day business through the bankingsystem that underpins <strong>it</strong>. As a minimum that <strong>mean</strong>s paying socialbenef<strong>it</strong>s through bank accounts or very close subst<strong>it</strong>utes <strong>and</strong> not inquasi-cash form.Addressing the issue of l<strong>it</strong>eracy – whether (i) financial ill<strong>it</strong>eracy thatcan lead to exclusion from developed banking services or (ii) morefundamental l<strong>it</strong>eracy problems that impede <strong>access</strong> to even the mostbasic services – is not an issue for <strong>banks</strong> alone.There are also a number of themes specific to advanced industrialeconomies:■■■Social exclusion for significant minor<strong>it</strong>y groups is a major problem inmany richer countries. Zero or lim<strong>it</strong>ed <strong>access</strong> to financial services isa key component of this that needs to be addressed. All countriesalready have some policy measures in place to extend at leastminimum banking services to otherwise excluded minor<strong>it</strong>ies. But these<strong>do</strong> not always work as well as intended. In particular, trying tom<strong>and</strong>ate <strong>access</strong> for socially excluded groups appears relatively<strong>mean</strong>ingless as take-up always seems to be disappointing. More workneeds to be <strong>do</strong>ne to find the real reasons why the un-banked feelbank accounts are not for them <strong>and</strong> why the poor feel locked intonon-bank financial services that often cost more than a properly runbank account <strong>and</strong> punish delinquency just as much.Post-offices <strong>and</strong> similar inst<strong>it</strong>utions w<strong>it</strong>h extensive networks generallyseem to be the explic<strong>it</strong> or implic<strong>it</strong> “back-stop” for these policies. But <strong>it</strong> isnot clear that this is e<strong>it</strong>her reasonable or effective. Much further thoughtis needed on this matter, especially where the post office <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> nothave w<strong>it</strong>hin <strong>it</strong>, or linked to <strong>it</strong>, properly const<strong>it</strong>uted banking operations.The impact of banking sector consolidation on <strong>access</strong> to finance seemsto be ambiguous. On the one h<strong>and</strong> consolidation, where <strong>it</strong> leads tobetter cost-efficiency, should allow <strong>banks</strong> to move on a prof<strong>it</strong>able basisinto business w<strong>it</strong>h customer groups that might otherwise be excluded.On the other h<strong>and</strong>, where consolidation <strong><strong>do</strong>es</strong> not lead to higher costefficiencyor where <strong>banks</strong> simply become too big to care for smallcustomers, peripheral regions etc., consolidation most probably has anegative impact on <strong>access</strong> to finance.120121


■■Financial deregulation has made cred<strong>it</strong> more <strong>access</strong>ible to more people.However, there seems to be an increasing division between (a) <strong>access</strong>to well regulated cred<strong>it</strong> on reasonable terms <strong>and</strong> (b) the <strong>access</strong> for morevulnerable <strong>and</strong> highly indebted low-income groups provided viaperipheral financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions w<strong>it</strong>h aggressive charging <strong>and</strong> foreclosurepractices. This matter also needs to be put on a sounder basis.The rapid spread of E-finance is putting trad<strong>it</strong>ional regulatory structuresunder great stress. Although <strong>it</strong> is assumed that this revolution willimprove <strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> lower costs <strong>it</strong> also creates considerable dangers forthe qual<strong>it</strong>y of financial services that some users receive; for the secur<strong>it</strong>yof funds; <strong>and</strong> for st<strong>and</strong>ards of information <strong>and</strong> privacy. The rapidlowering of interest margins that is expected to accompany the sprea<strong>do</strong>f E-finance may also put stress on financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions that havetrad<strong>it</strong>ionally maintained a strong social agenda as part of theiroperating m<strong>and</strong>ate.There are also a number of themes specific to developing <strong>and</strong> emergingmarket economies:■■■Developing country governments need increasingly to a<strong>do</strong>pt a broadervision about the role of particular financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions in helpingto move levels of financial <strong>access</strong> closer to those found in the richerindustrial countries.This is likely, in most cases, to involve measures to make mainstreamcommercial <strong>banks</strong> both more compet<strong>it</strong>ive <strong>and</strong> more cost efficient.Clearly, <strong>how</strong>ever, purely shareholder-value driven inst<strong>it</strong>utions maymake different use of the opportun<strong>it</strong>ies provided by improved costeffectivenessthan will mission-oriented proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong>, but bothmust address the issue of cost-effectiveness if they are to have any realchance of servicing the higher volume, lower value transactions ofthose w<strong>it</strong>h l<strong>it</strong>tle or no current <strong>access</strong> to financial services.It also needs to involve a very serious reconsideration of the role ofnear-<strong>banks</strong> that in the past have been viewed as the main platform tosupport various social agendas including improved financial <strong>access</strong> formore people. In many countries this will need to involve a muchclearer <strong>and</strong> reliable regulatory structure for microfinance inst<strong>it</strong>utionsthat stresses above all the need for such inst<strong>it</strong>utions to be financiallysustainable for the long term.■ The depos<strong>it</strong>-mobilisation functions of microfinance inst<strong>it</strong>utions certainlyneed to be stressed as highly as their cred<strong>it</strong> functions. The new approachwill also need to take on board the changing organisational structuresof microfinance inst<strong>it</strong>utions <strong>and</strong> above all their greater integration <strong>and</strong>overlap w<strong>it</strong>h other parts of the financial system. This will help toensure a more compet<strong>it</strong>ive overall financial system.■ As a part of this process there will also need to be a reconsiderationof the role of state-owned inst<strong>it</strong>utions that have the capac<strong>it</strong>y to reachout to mass markets. In some countries this reconsideration will bearound the question of whether an existing postal <strong>savings</strong> bank canmove beyond a lim<strong>it</strong>ed depos<strong>it</strong>-mobilisation function <strong>and</strong> closer tobroader-based retail banking. A pre-requis<strong>it</strong>e for this is to have postalbanking operations put onto a properly const<strong>it</strong>uted banking basis w<strong>it</strong>hring-fencing of customers’ depos<strong>it</strong>s plus proper settlements systems<strong>and</strong> balance sheet <strong>and</strong> risk management processes. In other countries,consideration should be given – at least as a temporary pragmaticsolution – to maintaining state-ownership of inst<strong>it</strong>utions that <strong>do</strong>provide mass-<strong>access</strong> to finance for groups not well served bycommercial <strong>banks</strong>. A cr<strong>it</strong>ical precond<strong>it</strong>ion to this would, <strong>how</strong>ever, haveto be that good Corporate Governance is guaranteed <strong>and</strong> the cost tothese <strong>banks</strong>’ of their social mission, the so-called “Social Dividend”, ismade clear <strong>and</strong> transparent in all their reporting.■ The E-Finance revolution creates huge <strong>and</strong> exc<strong>it</strong>ing opportun<strong>it</strong>iesrapidly to leap-frog some of the defic<strong>it</strong> in financial <strong>access</strong> that weobserve today. But the realisation of this potential will require earlyopening up of telephone services to more new entry <strong>and</strong> to freerpricing. Thereafter there is a daunting agenda of regulatory measuresto ensure that the potentially explosive growth avoids some of theobvious p<strong>it</strong>falls of financial instabil<strong>it</strong>y, insecur<strong>it</strong>y of funds, <strong>and</strong> thepremature demise of more trad<strong>it</strong>ional but fragile inst<strong>it</strong>utions that canplay some part in improving <strong>access</strong>.The table on the following page draws together these issues in the formof a policy matrix, identifying what different players might contribute tothe process of improving <strong>access</strong>.122123


Table 15: Outline Policy Matrix: responsibil<strong>it</strong>ies <strong>and</strong> timescalesNEAR-TERMMEDIUM-TERMLONG-TERM/ONGOING- Insert <strong>access</strong>agenda into widerregulatory agendaplus debate aboutstate ownership <strong>and</strong>compet<strong>it</strong>ion policy- Build on work ofCGAP to integrate<strong>banks</strong> into microfinanceagendaSupra-nationalInst<strong>it</strong>utions- Co-ordinateestimates of truelevels of <strong>access</strong>(<strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> MFIs)- Bolster assessmentof levels of, <strong>and</strong>obstacles to <strong>access</strong>in IMF/ World BankFSAP programme(including impactof AML/ant<strong>it</strong>errorist)- Assess local levelsof <strong>access</strong>- Immediately reviewlocal AML/ant<strong>it</strong>erroristrules- Scope l<strong>it</strong>eracyrequirements- Build links w<strong>it</strong>hlocal microfinanceindustry bodies- Supportrefinancing/buy-outs of MFIcred<strong>it</strong> portfolios by<strong>banks</strong> w<strong>it</strong>h retaildepos<strong>it</strong>-takingcapac<strong>it</strong>y- Develop supranationaldatabasesfor benchmarking<strong>access</strong> levels <strong>and</strong>cost of <strong>access</strong>- Refine reportingsystems to track<strong>access</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>it</strong>s cost- Develop financiall<strong>it</strong>eracy programme- Explore scope forgearing up existinginter<strong>banks</strong>ettlement systemsto support basic<strong>access</strong> products- Explore rolloutof rem<strong>it</strong>tancesproduct alreadyin Spain- Build links w<strong>it</strong>hmicrofinancebodies- Build on existing<strong>savings</strong> products toallow for collectivesaving by membersof MFIs- Develop affordablelocal rem<strong>it</strong>tances- Roll-out locall<strong>it</strong>eracyprogrammesREFERENCES/BIBLIOGRAPHY- Association of Br<strong>it</strong>ish Insurers (1999) ‘Financial Exclusion – an ABIAnalysis of the Background <strong>and</strong> Issues to Aid Industry Discussion’(quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong>Research Review, 2000).National Author<strong>it</strong>iesBanking Industries(collectively)Proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong>(collectively)Proxim<strong>it</strong>y <strong>banks</strong>(individually)- Scope contributionto <strong>access</strong> agenda- Share best practiceon buildingfinancial l<strong>it</strong>eracy- Identify own role inmaintaining <strong>access</strong>particularly inremote rural areas- Try <strong>and</strong> negotiatestreamlined ‘knowyour customer’rules to reflectspecial nature ofcustomer base- Reduce licensing/regulatory/taxburden on SMEs- Pay state wages/benef<strong>it</strong>s via <strong>banks</strong>- Roll out basic<strong>access</strong> productsw<strong>it</strong>h st<strong>and</strong>ardisedfeatures backed bycommon l<strong>it</strong>eracyprogramme- Develop guidanceon cred<strong>it</strong> portfoliorefinancing/buy-outfrom MFIs w<strong>it</strong>houtdepos<strong>it</strong>-takingcapac<strong>it</strong>y- Participate indevelopment ofbasic national<strong>access</strong> products,opening upnetwork to other<strong>banks</strong> for realisticfees- Develop affordableinternationalrem<strong>it</strong>tancesproduct- Atkin, M., <strong>and</strong> J. Glen, (1992), ‘Comparing Corporate Cap<strong>it</strong>al Structurearound the Globe’, The International Executive, vol 34.- Avery, R., R.W. Bostic <strong>and</strong> G.B Carter, (2000), The Performance <strong>and</strong>Prof<strong>it</strong>abil<strong>it</strong>y of CRA-Related Lending, Federal Reserve Bank ofClevel<strong>and</strong> web s<strong>it</strong>e (www.clevel<strong>and</strong>.org/research).- Barclay, M. <strong>and</strong> W. Sm<strong>it</strong>h, (1995), ‘The matur<strong>it</strong>y structure of corporatedebt’, Journal of Finance.- Bata, G., D. Kaufmann, <strong>and</strong> A. Stone, (2001), ‘Voice of the firm 2000:Investment climate <strong>and</strong> government findings of the world businessenvironment survey (WBES)’, Mimeo, World Bank.- Baydas, M., D. Graham <strong>and</strong> L.Valenzuela (1998), ‘Commercial Banksin Microfinance: New Actors in the Microfinance World.’ DevelopmentAlternative Inc, Bethseda, US.- Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, R. Levine, <strong>and</strong> V. Maskimovic, (2000),‘Financial structure <strong>and</strong> economic development: firm, industry <strong>and</strong>country evidence’, World Bank Working Paper No. 2423.- Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, R. Levine, (2000), ‘A New Database on theStructure <strong>and</strong> Development of the Financial Sector’ The World BankEconomic Review No.14: pp 597-605.124125


- Beck, T, A Demirgüç-Kunt, <strong>and</strong> R Levine (2004), ‘Finance <strong>and</strong> Poverty:Cross-Country Evidence’, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper3338.- Beck, T, A Demirgüç-Kunt, <strong>and</strong> M S Martinez Peria (2005), ‘Reachingout: Access to <strong>and</strong> use of banking services across countries’,World Bank Policy Research.- Beck, T <strong>and</strong> A de la Torre, (2005 forthcoming), ‘The Analytics of Accessto Finance: Introducing the Access Possibil<strong>it</strong>ies Frontier’, World BankPolicy Research.- Beck, T, R Levine, <strong>and</strong> N Loayza, (2000), ‘Finance <strong>and</strong> the Sources ofGrowth’, Journal of Financial Economics 58 (1-2), 261-300.- Beck, T., R. Levine <strong>and</strong> N.A. Loayza, (2000), Financial Interrmediation<strong>and</strong> Growth: Causalties <strong>and</strong> Causes. Journal of Monetary Economics,August 2000: pp 31-77 <strong>and</strong> web s<strong>it</strong>e www.worldbank.org/research/growth/lbdata.htm.- Berger, A. N., I Hasan <strong>and</strong> L. F. Klapper, (2003), ‘Further Evidence onthe Link between Finance <strong>and</strong> Growth: An International Analysis ofCommun<strong>it</strong>y Banking <strong>and</strong> Economic Performance’, World BankWorking Paper, No 3105.- Kaushik Bhattacharya, K., ‘How good is the BankScope database?A cross-validation exercise w<strong>it</strong>h correction factors for marketconcentration measures’, Bank for International Settlements, WorkingPapers No 133.- Burtchardt, T. <strong>and</strong> J. Hills, (1997), ‘Private Welfare Insurance <strong>and</strong> SocialSecur<strong>it</strong>y: Pushing the Boundaries’ York: York Publishing Services (quotedin Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> ResearchReview, 2000).- Burton, D., (1996), ‘Ethnic<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> Consumer Financial Behaviour; A CaseStudy of Br<strong>it</strong>ish Asians in the Pensions Market’ International Journal ofBank Marketing, No14: pp 21-31 (quoted in Financial ServicesAuthor<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- Caskey, J. P., (2002) “Bringing Unbanked Households into the BankingSystem”, paper for the Brookings Inst<strong>it</strong>utions, Harvard Univers<strong>it</strong>y JointCenter for Housing Studies. Mimeo.- Caskey, J. P., (2002) “Bringing Unbanked Households into the BankingSystem”, paper for the Brookings Inst<strong>it</strong>utions, Harvard Univers<strong>it</strong>y JointCenter for Housing Studies. Mimeo.- Caskey, J. P., C. Ruiz Durán <strong>and</strong> T. M. Solo, (2004) “The Unbanked inMexico <strong>and</strong> the Un<strong>it</strong>ed States”, unpublished.- Christen, R. P., E. Rhyne, R. C. Vogel <strong>and</strong> C. McKean, (1996), ‘Maximizingthe Outreach of Microenterprise Finance – An Analysis of SuccessfulMicrofinance Programs’, Centre for Development Information <strong>and</strong>Evaluation, USAID Program <strong>and</strong> Operations Assessment Report, No.10, Washington, (quoted in Morduch, J. <strong>and</strong> B. Hayley, 2002, ‘Analysisof the Effects of Microfinance on Poverty Reduction’, NYU WagnerWorking Paper No. 1014).- Churchill, C., (2000), ‘Bulletin Highlights <strong>and</strong> Tables – Reaching thePoor’, The Microbanking Bulletin. Issue 5, (quoted in Morduch, J. <strong>and</strong>B. Hayley, 2002, ‘Analysis of the Effects of Microfinance on PovertyReduction’, NYU Wagner Working Paper No. 1014).- CGAP, [1998], ‘Commercial Banks in Microfinance: New Actors in theMicrofinance World’, Focus Paper No 12, World Bank ConsultativeGroup to Assist the Poorest.- CGAP, [2002], ‘Savings Are As Important As Cred<strong>it</strong>: Depos<strong>it</strong> ServicesFor The Poor’, Donor Brief No 4, World Bank Consultative Group toAssist the Poorest.- CGAP (2004), ‘Occasional Paper No 8 – Financial Inst<strong>it</strong>utions w<strong>it</strong>h a“Double Bottom Line”: Implications for the Future of Microfinance’,CGAP, Washington.- Claessens, S., T. Glaessner <strong>and</strong> D. Klingebiel, (2001), E-Finance in EmergingMarkets: Is Leapfrogging Possible? Financial Sector Discussion PaperNo. 7, World Bank.- Caskey, J. P., (1997), Lower Income American, Higher Cost FinancialServices, Madison, WI: Filene Research Inst<strong>it</strong>ute126127


- Cobham, D., <strong>and</strong> R. Subramaniam, (1995), ‘Corporate Finance inDeveloping Countries: New Evidence from India’, CRIEFF DiscussionPaper 9512.- Connolly, C. <strong>and</strong> H. Khal<strong>do</strong>un, (2001), ‘Financial Services <strong>and</strong> SocialExclusion’, Chifley Research Centre, Univers<strong>it</strong>y of New South Wales.- Cook, P., <strong>and</strong> F. Nixson, (2000), ‘Finance <strong>and</strong> Small <strong>and</strong> Medium-SizedEnterprise Development’, Paper No. 14, Finance <strong>and</strong> DevelopmentResearch Programme, Working Paper Series.- Consumer Cred<strong>it</strong> Association (1999) ‘Combating Financial Exclusion:The Role of the Home Cred<strong>it</strong> Industry’ Submission prepared by theConsumer Cred<strong>it</strong> Association to Treasury Policy Action Team 14.(quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong>Research Review, 2000).- Degryse, H., N. Masschelein <strong>and</strong> J. M<strong>it</strong>chell, (2004), ‘SMEs <strong>and</strong> BankLending Relationships <strong>and</strong> the Impact of Mergers’, National Bank ofBelgium Working Paper No. 46.- Demirguc-Kunt, A. <strong>and</strong> V. Maksimovic, (1996), ‘Inst<strong>it</strong>utions, financialmarkets, <strong>and</strong> firm’s choice of debt matur<strong>it</strong>y’, World Bank WorkingPaper No. 1686.- Disney, R., E. Grundy, <strong>and</strong> P. Johnson, (1997), ‘The Dynamics ofRetirement: analyses of the Retirement Surveys’ Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Departmentof Social Secur<strong>it</strong>y (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out?A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review 2000).- DSGV – Germany, (2001), Survey – Blue-Print on Medium-SizedEnterprises.- Eichengreen, B., Mussa, M., <strong>and</strong> others, (1998), Cap<strong>it</strong>al AccountLiberaliization: Theoretical <strong>and</strong> Practical Aspects, IMF Occasional PaperNo. 172.- EIM Business <strong>and</strong> Policy Research, [2004], www.wim.nl (tab throughto Observatory of European SMEs <strong>and</strong> European Network for Social<strong>and</strong> Economic Research (ENSR) survey data).- ESBG, (2003), ‘The Future of European Retail Banking Markets’,European Savings Banks Group, Brussels.128- EU – Commission Staff Working Paper (2003), ‘Creating anEntrepreneurial Europe – The Activ<strong>it</strong>ies of the European Union for Small<strong>and</strong> Medium-sized Enterprises’, European Commission, COM(2003) 26.- EU – Enterprise Policy Group (2004), ‘Microcred<strong>it</strong> for small businesses<strong>and</strong> business creation : bridging a market gap’.- Fern<strong>and</strong>o, N. A., (2003), ‘Do Governments in Asia have a role indevelopment of sustainable micro-finance services? Some views’,ADB mimeo.- Fern<strong>and</strong>o, N. A., (2003), ‘Micro-finance Industry: Experiences, Challenges,<strong>and</strong> Opportun<strong>it</strong>ies’, presentation to a Forum on Micro-finance , ADB.- Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y, (2000), In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong>Research Review.- Ford, J. <strong>and</strong> K. Rowlinson, (1996) ‘Low-Income Households <strong>and</strong> Cred<strong>it</strong>:Exclusion, Preference <strong>and</strong> Inclusion; Environment <strong>and</strong> Planning A,28: 1345-60 (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out?A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review 2000).- Galbis, V., (1977), “Financial Intermediation <strong>and</strong> Economic Growthin Less-Developed Countries: A Theoretical Approach, Journal ofDevelopment Studies, 13(2), pp.58-72.- Gibbons, D. S. <strong>and</strong> J. W. Meehan, (2000), ‘The Microcred<strong>it</strong> Summ<strong>it</strong>Challenge: Working Towards Inst<strong>it</strong>utional Financial Self-Sufficiencywhile Maintaining a Comm<strong>it</strong>ment to Serving the Poorest Families’,www.microcred<strong>it</strong>summ<strong>it</strong>.org/papers/papers.htm, (quoted in Morduch,J. <strong>and</strong> B. Hayley, 2002, ‘Analysis of the Effects of Microfinance on PovertyReduction’, NYU Wagner Working Paper No. 1014).- Gloukoviezoff, G., (2003), L’exclusion bancaire et financiere desparticulars, Les Travaux de l’Observatoire, Centre Walras, Lyon.- Gloukoviezoff, G., (2004), ‘La médiation de proxim<strong>it</strong>é, une réponseà l’exclusion bancaire?’, FORS-Recherche Sociale, n°169, Paris.- Goldsm<strong>it</strong>h, R. W., (1969), Financial Structure <strong>and</strong> EconomicDevelopment, Yale Univers<strong>it</strong>y Press, New Haven.129


- Goodhart, C. A. E., (1975), Money, Information <strong>and</strong> Uncertainty,MacMillan, Lon<strong>do</strong>n.- Greenwood, J. <strong>and</strong> B. Jovanovic, (1990), “Financial Development,Growth <strong>and</strong> the Distribution of Income,” Journal of Pol<strong>it</strong>ical Economy,98 (5,Pt 1) pp.1076-1107.- Hashemi, S., S. Schuler <strong>and</strong> I. Riley, (1996), ‘Rural Cred<strong>it</strong> Programs <strong>and</strong>Women’s Empowerment in Bangladesh’ in World DevelopmentVol. 24, No. 4 pp. 635-653.- Hedges, A., (1998), ‘Pensions <strong>and</strong> retirement Planning; Lon<strong>do</strong>n:Department of Social Secur<strong>it</strong>y (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>yIn or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- Her Majesty’s Treasury, (1999), Access to Financial Services, Lon<strong>do</strong>n.HM Treasury.- Hicks, J. R., (1969), The Theory of Economic History, Oxford,Claren<strong>do</strong>n Press.- Honohan, P (2004), ‘Working Paper No. 43 – Financial Sector Policy <strong>and</strong>the Poor: Selected Findings <strong>and</strong> Issues’, World Bank, Washington.- Honohan, P (2004b), ‘Measuring Microfinance Access: Building onExisting Cross-Country Data – A Paper for UNDP, World Bank <strong>and</strong>IMF Workshop on Data on the Access of Poor <strong>and</strong> Low Income Peopleto Financial Services’, World Bank, Washington.- Hulme, D. <strong>and</strong> P. Mosley, (1996), ‘Finance against Poverty - Volume 2’(quoted in M &H 2002).- IDEA Consult, (2003), ‘Evaluation of the Commission action toPromote the Development of Mutual Guarantee Schemes <strong>and</strong> theirUse by SMEs in the EU’, N° ENTR/01/059.- IFC, (2002), The Private Sector Financing Activ<strong>it</strong>ies of InternationalFinancial Inst<strong>it</strong>utions – 2001 update, International Finance Corporation.- Kader, F., (2001), ‘Rating MFIs in Relation to Sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y Issues inMicrocred<strong>it</strong>’ in ‘Challenges for Second Generation: Regulation,Supervision <strong>and</strong> Resource Mobilization’, Sharif, I <strong>and</strong> G. Wood (eds),Univers<strong>it</strong>y Press Lim<strong>it</strong>ed.- Kempson, E, (1997), ‘Underst<strong>and</strong>ing Financial Exclusion’ (quoted inFinancial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> ResearchReview 2000).- Kempson, E, (1998), ‘Savings <strong>and</strong> Low Income <strong>and</strong> Ethnic Minor<strong>it</strong>yHouseholds’ Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Personal Investment Author<strong>it</strong>y (quoted inFinancial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> ResearchReview, 2000).- Kempson, E., A. Bryson <strong>and</strong> K. Rowlingson, (1994) ‘Hard Times?’Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Policy Studies Inst<strong>it</strong>ute (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>yIn or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- Kempson, E <strong>and</strong> C. Whyley, (1998) ‘Access to Current Accounts’,Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Br<strong>it</strong>ish Bankers Association (quoted in Financial ServicesAuthor<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000) .- Kempson, E. <strong>and</strong> C. Whyley, (2000) ‘Extortionate Cred<strong>it</strong> in the UK’Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Department of Trade <strong>and</strong> Industry (quoted in Financial ServicesAuthor<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- Kh<strong>and</strong>ker, S., (1998), ‘Fighting Poverty w<strong>it</strong>h Microcred<strong>it</strong>.’ OxfordUnivers<strong>it</strong>y Press.- Kader, F., (2001), ‘Rating MFIs in Relation to Sustainabil<strong>it</strong>y Issues inMicrocred<strong>it</strong>’ in ‘Challenges for Second Generation: Regulation,Supervision <strong>and</strong> Resource Mobilization’ by Sharif, I <strong>and</strong> G. Wood (eds)Univers<strong>it</strong>y Press Lim<strong>it</strong>ed.- King, R. G. <strong>and</strong> R. Levine, (1993), “Finance <strong>and</strong> Growth: SchumpeterMight be Right,” Quarterly Journal of Economics,108(3), pp717-738.- KIPPRA, (2001), Legal <strong>and</strong> Other Constraints on Access to FinancialServices in Kenya, Kippra Special Report, Nairobi.130131


- Laeven, L., (2000), ‘Financial liberalization <strong>and</strong> financing constraints:evidence from panel data on emerging economies’, World BankWorking Paper No. 2467.- Laporta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Schleifer <strong>and</strong> R. W. Vishny, (1996),“Law <strong>and</strong> Finance”, National Bureau of Economic Research No. 5561.- Le Monde, (2004 – 9th June), “Cinq millions de personnes en Francesont des exclus bancaires.”- Levine, R., (1996), Financial Development <strong>and</strong> Economic Growth:Views <strong>and</strong> Agenda, Policy Research Working Papers No. 1678,World Bank.- Levine, R. <strong>and</strong> S. Zervos, (1998), Stock Markets, Banks <strong>and</strong> EconomicGrowth, American Economic Review, 88 (3), pp 537-58.- Leyson, A. <strong>and</strong> N. Thrift, (1993) ‘The Restructuring of the UK FinancialServices Industry in the 1990s: A Reversal of Fortune: Journal of Ruralstudies, 9: 223-41 (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out?A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review 2000).- Leyson, A. And N. Thrift, (1995), ‘Geographies of Financial Exclusion:Financial Ab<strong>and</strong>onment in Br<strong>it</strong>ain <strong>and</strong> the Un<strong>it</strong>ed States’ Transactionsof the Inst<strong>it</strong>ute of Br<strong>it</strong>ish Geographers, new Series, 20: 312-41).- Leyshon, A. <strong>and</strong> N. Thrift, (1993), “The restructuring of the UKfinancial services industry in the 1990s: A reversal of fortune? Journalof Rural Studies, No 9, pp 223-41.- Loayza, N., H. Lopez, K. Schmidt-Hebbel <strong>and</strong> L. Serven, (1998),World Savings Database, mimeo, World Bank.- Lynch, M. <strong>and</strong> L. Haidar, (1998), ‘UK report In J. Evers <strong>and</strong> UU. Reifner(Eds) ‘The Social Responsibil<strong>it</strong>y of Cred<strong>it</strong> Inst<strong>it</strong>utions in the Eu. BadenBaden; Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft.- McKinnon, R. I., (1973), Money <strong>and</strong> Cap<strong>it</strong>al in Economic Development,Brookings Inst<strong>it</strong>ution, Washington DC.- Merton, R. C., (1992), “Financial Innovation <strong>and</strong> Economic Performance,”Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, No 4(4) pp12-22.- Merton, R. C., <strong>and</strong> B. Zvi, (1995), “A Conceptual Framework forAnalyzing the Financial Environment” in The Global Financial System:A Functional Perspective, eds. D. B. Crane, et al., Boston Ma, HarvardBusiness School Press, 45(1), pp. 31-48.- Modigliani, F. <strong>and</strong> M. Miller, (1958), ‘The cost of cap<strong>it</strong>al, corporationfinance, <strong>and</strong> the theory of investment’, American Economic Review.- McKay, S., (1992) ‘Pensioners Asses’ Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Policy Studies Inst<strong>it</strong>ute(quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong>Research Review 2000).- Montgomery, R., D. Bhattacharya <strong>and</strong> D. Hulme, (1996), ‘Cred<strong>it</strong> forthe Poor in Bangladesh: The BRAC Rural Development Program<strong>mean</strong>d the Government Thana Resource Development <strong>and</strong> EmploymentProgramme’ in ‘Finance Against Poverty’ by Hulme D. <strong>and</strong> P. Mosley(eds), Vols 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, Routledge, Lon<strong>do</strong>n.- Morduch, J., (1998), ‘Does Microfinance Really Help the Poor: NewEvidence from Flagship Programs in Bangladesh’, Dept. of Economics<strong>and</strong> HIID, Harvard Univers<strong>it</strong>y <strong>and</strong> Hoover Inst<strong>it</strong>ution, Stanford Univers<strong>it</strong>y.- Morduch, J. <strong>and</strong> B. Hayley, (2002), ‘Analysis of the Effects of Microfinanceon Poverty Reduction’, NYU Wagner Working Paper No. 1014.- National Consumer Council, (1995), ‘Financial Services <strong>and</strong> Low-Income Consumers’ Lon<strong>do</strong>n: National Consumer Council (quoted inFinancial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> ResearchReview, 2000) .- Nat West, (1999), ‘Education is the Key to Success of StakeholderPensions (Press Release) (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In orOut? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- Nedbank, [2004], ‘The South African Financial Services Charter –Banking the Unbanked‘, Presentation to 10th WSBI Africa GroupRegional Meeting.- Office of Fair Trading, (1997), ‘Report of the Director General’s Inquiryinto pensions’ Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Offrice of Fair Trading (quoted in FinancialServices Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).132133


- Office of Fair Trading, (1999a), ‘ The Consumer Survey. Rep. No. OFT 255d.Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Office of Fair Trading (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>yIn or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review 2000).- Office of Fair Trading, (1999b), ‘Qual<strong>it</strong>ative Research into EthnicMinor<strong>it</strong>ies <strong>and</strong> Financial Services. Rep. No. OFT 255e. Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Office ofFair Trading (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature<strong>and</strong> Research Review 2000).- Opinion Leader Research, (1999), ‘Home Cred<strong>it</strong>: Bridging the Gap inUnderst<strong>and</strong>ing’ Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Opinion Leader Research (quoted in FinancialServices Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- PA Consulting, (2004), ‘Consolidation Can’t Save Germany’s Banks’,The Wall Street Journal Europe (April 26 ed<strong>it</strong>ion).- Paulson, J. A. <strong>and</strong> J. McAndrews, (1998), ‘Financial Services for theUrban Poor – South Africa’s E Plan’, World Bank working Paper, No 449.- Peachey, S., (2004), Comment, Government of Kenya Stakeholders’Forum on Financial Sector Reforms, Mombassa.- Pegram Walters Associates, (1995), ‘Pensions Public<strong>it</strong>y Qual<strong>it</strong>ativeresearch: A Final Report’ Rep. No. PWA 3817. Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Pegram WaltersAssociates (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature<strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- Personal Investment Author<strong>it</strong>y, (1997), ‘Consumer Panel Report Lon<strong>do</strong>n:Personal Investment Author<strong>it</strong>y‘ (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>yIn or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- Pesaresi, N. <strong>and</strong> O. Pilley, (2003), ‘Retail banking, social exclusion <strong>and</strong>public service’, EU Directorate-General - Compet<strong>it</strong>ion.- Pomerleano, M., (1998), ‘Corporate Finance Lessons from the AsianCrisis’, Public Policy for the Private Sector, Note No. 155, World Bank.- Prasad, S., C.J. Green, <strong>and</strong> V. Murinde, ‘Company Financing, Cap<strong>it</strong>alStructure, <strong>and</strong> Ownership: A Survey, <strong>and</strong> Implications for DevelopingEconomies’, HM Treasury, 2001.- Prasad, S., K. Rogoff, S-J Wei <strong>and</strong> M. A. Kose, (2003), ‘Effects of FinancialGlobalization on Developing Countries: Some Empirical Evidence’, IMFOccasional paper No. 220.- Rajan, R. <strong>and</strong> L. Zingales, (1995), ‘<strong>What</strong> <strong>do</strong> we know about cap<strong>it</strong>alstructure? Some evidence from international data’, Journal of Finance.- Roe, A. R., S. Peachey, et al., (2003), ‘Bank Consolidation In theECA Region: A Multicountry Study: Summary Report’, World Bank(unpublished).- Roe, A. R., (2004), ‘Key Issues In The Future Development Of KenyanBanking‘, Paper to Government of Kenya Stakeholders’ Forum onFinancial Sector Reforms, Mombassa.- Roubini, N., <strong>and</strong> X. Sala-i-Martin, (1992), ‘Financial Repression <strong>and</strong>Economic Growth’, Journal of Development Economics, No 39 (1),pp 5-30.- Rowlingson, K., (1994), ‘Moneylenders <strong>and</strong> their Customers’, PolicyStudies Inst<strong>it</strong>ute, Lon<strong>do</strong>n, (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>yIn or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- Rowlingson, K., C. Whyley <strong>and</strong> T. Warren, (1999), ‘Wealth in Br<strong>it</strong>ain -A Lifecycle Perspective’, Policy Studies Inst<strong>it</strong>ute, Lon<strong>do</strong>n, (quoted inFinancial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> ResearchReview, 2000).- Schiffer, M., <strong>and</strong> B. Weder, ‘(2001), ‘Firm Size <strong>and</strong> the BusinessEnvironment: Worldwide Survey Results’, IFC Discussion Paper No 43.- Schumpeter, J. A., (1912), ‘The Theory of Economic Development’translation by Opie, R., Cambridge, Ma., Harvard Univers<strong>it</strong>y Press, 1934.- Shyam-Sunder, L. <strong>and</strong> S. Myers, (1999), ‘Testing static trade-off againstpecking order models of cap<strong>it</strong>al structure’, Journal of FinancialEconomics.- Singh, A., (1995), ‘Corporate Financing Patterns in IndustrialisingEconomies: A Comparative International Study’, IFC Technical PaperNo. 2.134135


- Solo, T. M., (2001), ‘Broadening Access to Financial Services Amongthe Urban Population: Mexico C<strong>it</strong>y’s Unbanked’, World Bankunpublished.- Speak, S. <strong>and</strong> S. Graham, (2000), ‘Service Not Included: SocialImplications of Private Sector Service Restructuring in MarginalisedNeighbourhoods’, Policy Press, Bristol, (quoted in Financial ServicesAuthor<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- de Soto, H, (2000), ‘The Mystery of Cap<strong>it</strong>al: Why Cap<strong>it</strong>alism Triumphsin the West <strong>and</strong> Fails Everywhere Else’, New York: Basic Books <strong>and</strong>Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Bantam Press/R<strong>and</strong>om House.- Srivinasan, S., (1995), ‘ROSCAs among South Asians in Oxford’ in‘Money-go-round’, S. Ardener <strong>and</strong> S Burman (eds.), pp. 199-208,Berg, Oxford, (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out?A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- Sterling, L., (1995), ‘Partners: the Social Organisation of RotatingSavings <strong>and</strong> Cred<strong>it</strong> Societies Among Exile Jamaicans’. Sociology, 29:pp 653-66 (quoted in Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out?A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- Pesaresi, N. <strong>and</strong> O. Pilley, (2003), ‘Retail banking, social exclusion <strong>and</strong>public service’, EU Directorate-General - Compet<strong>it</strong>ion.- Stone, R (2005), ‘Financial Access Indicators Stocktake: A paper forDepartment for International Development’, Emerging MarketEconomics, Lon<strong>do</strong>n.- Schumkler, S., <strong>and</strong> E. Vesperoni, (2001), ‘Globalization <strong>and</strong> Firms’Financing Choices: Evidence from Emerging Economies’, World Bank.- Sharif, I. <strong>and</strong> G. Wood. (2001) ‘Challenges of Second GenerationMicrofinance: Resource Mobilisation, Regulation <strong>and</strong> Supervision.’UPL, Dhaka.- Vass, J. (1997) ‘Savings <strong>and</strong> Investments for Low-Income Consumers’Lon<strong>do</strong>n: National Consumer Council (quoted in Financial ServicesAuthor<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- Warburton, P., (2000), ‘Debt <strong>and</strong> Delusion’, Penguin Books, 2nd Ed<strong>it</strong>ion.- World Bank, (1989), ‘Financial Systems <strong>and</strong> Development, WorldDevelopment Report’, Oxford Univers<strong>it</strong>y Press <strong>and</strong> World Bank,Lon<strong>do</strong>n <strong>and</strong> Washington DC.- World Bank, (2000), ‘Poverty, World Development Report’, OxfordUnivers<strong>it</strong>y Press <strong>and</strong> World Bank, Lon<strong>do</strong>n <strong>and</strong> Washington DC.- World Bank, (2002), ‘Inst<strong>it</strong>utions for Development, World DevelopmentReport’, Oxford Univers<strong>it</strong>y Press <strong>and</strong> World Bank, Lon<strong>do</strong>n <strong>and</strong>Washington DC.- Whyley, C., J. McCormick <strong>and</strong> E. Kempson, (1998), ‘Paying for Peaceof Mind’ Lon<strong>do</strong>n: Policy Studies Inst<strong>it</strong>ute (quoted in Financial ServicesAuthor<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> Research Review, 2000).- Wood, C., (1999), ‘Pensions for All’, Pearl Assurance, Lon<strong>do</strong>n, (quotedin Financial Services Author<strong>it</strong>y In or Out? A L<strong>it</strong>erature <strong>and</strong> ResearchReview, 2000).- Wright, G. A. N., (2000), ‘Microfinance Systems: Designing Qual<strong>it</strong>yFinancial Services for the Poor’, Zed Books Ltd. Lon<strong>do</strong>n & New York,<strong>and</strong> The Univers<strong>it</strong>y Press Lim<strong>it</strong>ed, Dhaka, (quoted in Morduch, J. <strong>and</strong>B. Hayley, 2002, ‘Analysis of the Effects of Microfinance on PovertyReduction’, NYU Wagner Working Paper No. 1014).- WSBI (2003), ‘Madrid Declaration 20th World Congress of SavingsBanks – Savings Banks: Efficiency <strong>and</strong> Comm<strong>it</strong>ment to Society’.- WSBI (2004), ‘The Provision of Microfinance Services by Savings Banks:Selected experiences from Africa, Asia <strong>and</strong> Latin America – A study forthe WSBI by Antonique Koning <strong>and</strong> Hugues Kamewe’, WSBI, Brussels.- WSBI (2004), ‘Access to Finance – A study for the WSBI by StephenPeachey <strong>and</strong> Alan Roe’, WSBI Research, Brussels.- WSBI (2005), ‘Access to Finance – Measuring the Contribution ofSavings Banks’, A Study for the WSBI by Stephen Peachey <strong>and</strong> AlanRoe – Oxford Policy Management-, WSBI Research, Brussels.- Zaman, H., (1998), ‘Assessing the Impact of Micro-cred<strong>it</strong> on Poverty<strong>and</strong> Vulnerabil<strong>it</strong>y in Bangladesh’, World Bank Policy Research WorkingPaper no. 2145.136137


About WSBI (World Savings Banks Inst<strong>it</strong>ute) <strong>and</strong>ESBG (European Savings Banks Group)WSBI (World Savings Banks Inst<strong>it</strong>ute) is one of the largest international bankingassociations <strong>and</strong> the only global representative of <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> retail <strong>banks</strong>.Founded in 1924, <strong>it</strong> represents <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> retail <strong>banks</strong> <strong>and</strong> associationsthereof in 84 countries of the world (Asia-Pacific, the Americas, Africa <strong>and</strong>Europe -via the European Savings Banks Group).It works closely w<strong>it</strong>h international financial inst<strong>it</strong>utions <strong>and</strong> <strong>do</strong>nor agencies<strong>and</strong> facil<strong>it</strong>ates the provision of <strong>access</strong> to financial sectors worldwide - be <strong>it</strong>in developing or developed regions. At the start of 2004, assets of member<strong>banks</strong> amounted to more than €7,300 billion.ESBG (European Savings Banks Group) is an international banking associationthat represents one of the largest European retail banking networks,comprising about one third of the retail banking market in Europe, w<strong>it</strong>h totalassets of €4,345 billion (1 January 2004). It represents the interests of <strong>it</strong>smembers vis-à-vis the EU Inst<strong>it</strong>utions <strong>and</strong> generates, facil<strong>it</strong>ates <strong>and</strong> manageshigh qual<strong>it</strong>y cross-border banking projects.WSBI-ESBG members are typically <strong>savings</strong> <strong>and</strong> retail <strong>banks</strong> or associationsthereof. They are often organised in decentralised networks <strong>and</strong> offer theirservices throughout their region. WSBI members have reinvested responsiblyin their region for decades <strong>and</strong> are one distinct benchmark for corporate socialresponsibil<strong>it</strong>y activ<strong>it</strong>ies throughout Europe <strong>and</strong> the world.Rue Marie-Thérèse, 11 ■ B-1000 Brussels ■ Tel: +32 2 211 11 11 ■ Fax: +32 2 211 11 99info@<strong>savings</strong>-<strong>banks</strong>.com ■ www.<strong>savings</strong>-<strong>banks</strong>.comPublished by WSBI/ESBG. Copyright January 2006 ISSN 1782-396X

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!