12.07.2015 Views

a Heterogeneous Markov Chain Model for Wage Mobility in Austria

a Heterogeneous Markov Chain Model for Wage Mobility in Austria

a Heterogeneous Markov Chain Model for Wage Mobility in Austria

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

True and Spurious State Dependence <strong>in</strong>Earn<strong>in</strong>gs Transitions ∗Andrea Weber †July 2004AbstractThis paper focuses on the measurement of earn<strong>in</strong>gs mobility underspecial consideration of <strong>in</strong>dividual heterogeneity. We model transitionsbetween qu<strong>in</strong>tiles <strong>in</strong> the wage distribution by a first order <strong>Markov</strong> process.The model is estimated us<strong>in</strong>g a fixed effects dynamic panel procedurethat uses a m<strong>in</strong>imum of assumptions. Thus we are able to control <strong>for</strong>the effects of observed <strong>in</strong>dividual heterogeneity by <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g time-vary<strong>in</strong>gexogenous variables as well as <strong>for</strong> unobserved <strong>in</strong>dividual effects. The estimates,derived from a large adm<strong>in</strong>istrative panel <strong>for</strong> <strong>Austria</strong>, <strong>in</strong>dicate thatcontroll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>for</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual heterogeneity reduces persistence of earn<strong>in</strong>gs byat least 27%.Keywords: <strong>Wage</strong> mobility, <strong>Markov</strong> process, dynamic panel estimation, fixedeffects estimationJel classification: C23, C25, J31, J60∗ I would like to thank Helmut Hofer, Bo Honoré and Rudolf W<strong>in</strong>ter-Ebmer, participantsat the 10th Internationa Panel Data Conference <strong>in</strong> Berl<strong>in</strong>, July 2002, participants at theCAM workshop <strong>for</strong> dynamic panel data models, Copenhagen, January 2003, and sem<strong>in</strong>arparticipants <strong>in</strong> Vienna and L<strong>in</strong>z <strong>for</strong> many helpful comments and suggestions.† Institute <strong>for</strong> Advanced Studies, Department of Economics and F<strong>in</strong>ance, Stumpergasse56, A-1060 Vienna, phone: +43-1-59991-147, fax: +43-1-59991-163, e-mail: andrea.weber@ihs.ac.at


1 IntroductionThe <strong>in</strong>equality of <strong>in</strong>come and the persistence of low <strong>in</strong>come are important social<strong>in</strong>dicators. From the welfarist po<strong>in</strong>t of view the static picture of <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> a s<strong>in</strong>gle po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> time can only be completed by consider<strong>in</strong>g thedynamics of the <strong>in</strong>come distribution as well. Individual mobility <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>comedistribution gives an impression of the equality of opportunities <strong>in</strong> a society andit also <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>ms about the <strong>in</strong>come risks an <strong>in</strong>dividual faces by mov<strong>in</strong>g downwards<strong>in</strong> the distribution.Individual heterogeneity is an important issue when study<strong>in</strong>g earn<strong>in</strong>gs mobility.The persistence <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual earn<strong>in</strong>gs is comparable to many other economicsituations where we observe that an <strong>in</strong>dividual who has experienced an event <strong>in</strong>the past is more likely to experience that event <strong>in</strong> the future than an <strong>in</strong>dividualwho has not experienced that event. ? discusses two explanations <strong>for</strong> thisphenomenon. The first one is the presence of “true state dependence”, <strong>in</strong> thesense that the lagged state enters the model <strong>in</strong> a structural way as an explanatoryvariable. Industry or country wide wage barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and firm specific wageschemes could be reasons <strong>for</strong> true state dependence. The second explanationis that heterogeneity makes the <strong>in</strong>dividuals differ <strong>in</strong> their propensity to experiencethe event <strong>in</strong> all time periods. This would mean that part of the observedearn<strong>in</strong>gs persistence is due heterogeneity either <strong>in</strong> characteristics like sex or educationor <strong>in</strong> unobservable characteristics like motivation or ability. Heckmancalls the latter source of serial correlation ”spurious state dependence”.Earn<strong>in</strong>gs mobility is often measured at an aggregate level by calculat<strong>in</strong>g mobility<strong>in</strong>dices accord<strong>in</strong>g to several theoretical concepts (???). The <strong>in</strong>dices arehelpful <strong>for</strong> comparisons across countries or social groups. But the results oftendiffer accord<strong>in</strong>g to the mobility concepts used (?). To get a better <strong>in</strong>sight <strong>in</strong>tothe underly<strong>in</strong>g dynamics and to allow <strong>for</strong> heterogeneity among <strong>in</strong>dividuals itis preferable to model <strong>in</strong>dividual earn<strong>in</strong>gs processes directly. In the literaturewe f<strong>in</strong>d two ma<strong>in</strong> approaches to this end. The literature on earn<strong>in</strong>gs dynamicsuses cont<strong>in</strong>uous time series models <strong>for</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual earn<strong>in</strong>gs development. Severalauthors, among them ???, fit models to the covariance structure of earn<strong>in</strong>gsand estimate a permanent and a transitory component. 1 The models constra<strong>in</strong>the nature of earn<strong>in</strong>gs dynamics and assume a great deal of homogeneity <strong>in</strong>the dynamics across <strong>in</strong>dividuals. Recent developments <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly allow <strong>for</strong>heterogeneity (?) or <strong>for</strong> more complicated processes(???) to achieve a betterfit of the actual earn<strong>in</strong>gs distribution.1 ? discuss the most prom<strong>in</strong>ent papers <strong>in</strong> a summary.1


Whereas the first approach models earn<strong>in</strong>g levels, the second strand of literatureis concerned with movement between relative positions or ranks <strong>in</strong> thedistribution. Typically <strong>Markov</strong> processes are used to model transitions betweendiscrete earn<strong>in</strong>gs states. This approach explicitely models the dynamics of theprocess, but the problem is the <strong>in</strong>clusion of heterogeneity <strong>in</strong>to the model. Ina sem<strong>in</strong>al paper ? <strong>in</strong>vestigates transitions <strong>in</strong>to/out of low <strong>in</strong>come and allowsdifferent processes <strong>for</strong> stayers and movers. The advances of econometric technique<strong>in</strong> the estimation of discrete response panel data models make it feasibleto use more detailed models.Many authors still concentrate on transitionsbetween two <strong>in</strong>come states like poverty and non-poverty (??). ? model transitionsbetween earn<strong>in</strong>gs qu<strong>in</strong>tiles us<strong>in</strong>g a copula approach to reduce the numberof parameters. All these papers use random effects estimation to account <strong>for</strong>unobservable <strong>in</strong>dividual heterogeneity.The aim of this paper is to determ<strong>in</strong>e the degree of true state dependence <strong>in</strong>the measurement of earn<strong>in</strong>gs mobility. We model the dynamics of transitionsbetween wage qu<strong>in</strong>tiles as a first order <strong>Markov</strong> process, which is heterogeneousamong <strong>in</strong>dividuals. We adopt a fixed effects mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit estimation proceduredesigned by ?, which is based on conditional likelihood maximization. 2With this approach it is possible to consider explicitly the effects of observed andunobserved <strong>in</strong>dividual characteristics on the measure of wage mobility. <strong>Model</strong><strong>in</strong>gqu<strong>in</strong>tiles gives an impression of the entire wage distribution and does notfocus on the lower part of the distribution alone. The fixed effects approach hasthe advantage of leav<strong>in</strong>g the distribution of the <strong>in</strong>dividual effects and the correlationbetween the <strong>in</strong>dividual effects, the <strong>in</strong>itial state, and exogenous variablescompletely unspecified which may be crucial <strong>for</strong> the consistency of the estimatedparameters. A major challenge <strong>for</strong> the fixed effects approach is parameter <strong>in</strong>terpretation.Partial effects on the response probability or conditional mean arenot identified. There<strong>for</strong>e the economic importance of covariates, or the amountof state dependence are difficult to determ<strong>in</strong>e. We take different approaches tolearn from the estimation results as much as possible: by compar<strong>in</strong>g them to amodel not controll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>for</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual effects, giv<strong>in</strong>g an upper bound <strong>for</strong> a wagepersistency measure and by simulat<strong>in</strong>g wage profiles.We study wage dynamics <strong>for</strong> a large sample of <strong>Austria</strong>n employees who areobserved between 1986 and 1998. The data consist of a sample drawn fromthe <strong>Austria</strong>n social security records. This data source provides most accurate2 Similar estimation procedures are used by ? <strong>in</strong> a study of transitions between labor marketstates, ? analyz<strong>in</strong>g household brand choices, and ? study<strong>in</strong>g welfare participation and femalelabor <strong>for</strong>ce participation.2


wage <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation over a long time horizon but wages are top coded at thecontribution cap. 3The analysis of <strong>Austria</strong> is <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g because <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>ternational comparison ?f<strong>in</strong>d that wage mobility is particularly low <strong>in</strong> <strong>Austria</strong>. This is probably a consequenceof the highly centralized wage barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g system <strong>in</strong> <strong>Austria</strong>. Centralizedwage sett<strong>in</strong>g makes aggregate wages move accord<strong>in</strong>g to the macroeconomic conditionsbut it leaves the firms little room <strong>for</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual adjustments. Hence,the rigid wage system would imply that there is a high degree of genu<strong>in</strong>e statedependence <strong>in</strong> <strong>Austria</strong>n wages.The rema<strong>in</strong>der of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section wepresent the general model and two special cases <strong>in</strong> which only observed heterogeneityis allowed <strong>for</strong> or <strong>in</strong>dividuals are assumed homogeneous. In Section 3 wediscuss the choice of the estimation method and present the estimator. Section4 describes the data and the variables used <strong>in</strong> the model. Section 4 conta<strong>in</strong>sthe estimation results and Section 5 concludes.2 A model dist<strong>in</strong>guish<strong>in</strong>g true state dependence andheterogeneityTo describe transitions between categories of the wage distribution we adoptthe latent propensity framework a la ?. At each period, the latent variable y ∗ kitdenotes the propensity level to be <strong>in</strong> state k out of states 0, . . . , m <strong>for</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividuali at time t. In our case states are non-employment k = 0 and five wage qu<strong>in</strong>tilesk = 1, . . . , m with m = 5. We observe N <strong>in</strong>dividuals i at T + 1 po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> timet = 0, . . . , T . The propensity function is determ<strong>in</strong>ed byy ∗ kit = x itβ k +m∑γ jk 1{y i(t−1) = j} + α ki + ɛ kit (1)j=0where x it is a vector of observable personal characteristics, 1 is the <strong>in</strong>dicatorfunction, y i(t−1) <strong>in</strong>dicates the lagged state, y i(t−1) = j if the <strong>in</strong>dividual was<strong>in</strong> state j at t − 1, α ki is an unobservable <strong>in</strong>dividual specific effect and ɛ kitis an unobservable error term. The parameters of <strong>in</strong>terest to be estimatedare β = (β 0 , . . . , β m ) which give the <strong>in</strong>fluence of observed covariates on thepropensity of be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> each state and γ the coefficient on the lagged endogenous3 This makes it complicated to model cont<strong>in</strong>uous wage dynamics. One way out could be acensored dynamic panel data model by ?.3


variable. The parameter γ is allowed to depend upon both the lagged state andthe current state, so that there are <strong>in</strong> total m 2 feedback parameters and γ jkis the feedback effect when the state j at t − 1 is followed by the state k attime t, where j, k ∈ 0, . . . , m. In the model γ represents true state dependencewhereas α i = (α 0i , . . . , α mi ) represents the source of spurious state dependence.We model <strong>in</strong>dividual heterogeneity depend<strong>in</strong>g on the state: each <strong>in</strong>dividual hasa specific propensity <strong>for</strong> each alternative.The l<strong>in</strong>k between the latent and the observed variables is given by the devicethat the observed state has maximal propensity:y it = k if ykit ∗ = max (ylit ∗ )lAs a consequence, if we assume that the underly<strong>in</strong>g errors ɛ kit , are <strong>in</strong>dependentacross alternatives and over time conditional on (x i , α i , y i0 ) and identically distributedaccord<strong>in</strong>g to the Type1 extreme value distribution, the probability of<strong>in</strong>dividual i of be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> state k at time t, is given byP (y it = k|y i(t−1) = j, x i , α i ) =exp(x it β k + γ jk + α ki )1 + ∑ ml=1 exp(x itβ l + γ jl + α li )with x i = (x i0 , . . . , x it ). This implies that the transition matrix of this firstorder <strong>Markov</strong> process is heterogeneous between <strong>in</strong>dividuals.It is worth notic<strong>in</strong>g some special cases of the general model (1)• No unobserved heterogeneity α ki = α k∀ i = 1, . . . , Nm∑ykit ∗ = x itβ k + γ jk 1{y i(t−1) = j} + α k + ɛ kit (2)j=0This is a model where no unobserved <strong>in</strong>dividual heterogeneity is presentand hence it is of the <strong>for</strong>m of a standard mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit model. Ifunobserved heterogeneity is absent, this model yields consistent and efficientestimates of the transition parameters. If unobserved heterogeneityis, however, present <strong>in</strong> this model, the lagged state variables and the errorterms ɛ kit are not <strong>in</strong>dependent and the estimates are <strong>in</strong>consistent. We usethe comparison of the general model (1) with unobserved heterogeneityand the mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit model (2) to per<strong>for</strong>m a test <strong>for</strong> the presence ofunobserved heterogeneity.• No observed or unobserved heterogeneity α ki = α k and x it = 0 ∀ i =4


elationship with the unobserved heterogeneity. Drawbacks of this approachare, first, that the semi-parametric nature of fixed effects models may lead toestimates that are much less precise than the correspond<strong>in</strong>g random effects estimates.Second, the parameter estimates by this approach do not allow oneto calculate objects such as the average effect of the explanatory variables onthe probability that y it equals a certa<strong>in</strong> state, because this will depend on thedistribution of α i . 5To assess the practical relevance of the theoretical considerations some studiescompare fixed and random effects approaches to estimation dynamic b<strong>in</strong>aryresponse panel data models <strong>in</strong> empirical applications. ? evaluate alternativeapproaches to differentiat<strong>in</strong>g state dependence from spurious correlation. ?compare robustness of estimators across econometric methods and <strong>in</strong>vestigate<strong>in</strong> Monte Carlo simulations how sensitive the methods are to model misspecification.Both papers f<strong>in</strong>d that the size of estimated parameters varies considerablyacross estimation methods and that ignor<strong>in</strong>g the contribution of heterogeneityto the <strong>in</strong>itial sample observations leads to drastically overstated estimates ofstate dependence.In this paper we trade the convenience of a fully specified model and straight<strong>for</strong>ward parameter <strong>in</strong>terpretation aga<strong>in</strong>st the freedom from parametric restrictionson the unobserved heterogeneity and <strong>in</strong>itial conditions and use a fixedeffects approach. We implement the extension of the ? method <strong>for</strong> the case ofmult<strong>in</strong>omial discrete choice variables, which covers our model <strong>for</strong> wage mobility.6The <strong>in</strong>dividual fixed effects parameters α ik <strong>in</strong> the general model (1) cannotbe estimated consistently. Unlike <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>ear models the problem of <strong>in</strong>cidentalvariables cannot be overcome by differenc<strong>in</strong>g. The idea applied by ? <strong>for</strong> fixedeffects logit estimation was to derive a set of conditional probabilities that donot depend on the <strong>in</strong>dividual effects. ? follow up on this approach. They regardevents where the state variable y switches from say state k to state l or reversebetween two po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> time, say s and t with 1 ≤ t < s ≤ T − 1. Conditional onsuch a switch and on the constancy of the explanatory variables <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>gperiods x i(t+1) = x i(s+1) , the probabilities of the events are <strong>in</strong>dependent ofthe <strong>in</strong>dividual effects. As the equality assumption may be too restrictive <strong>for</strong>5 The discussion about fixed effects versus random effects estimation <strong>in</strong> dynamic discretechoice models has been enriched by recent paper by ? who propose to estimate boundsparameters <strong>in</strong> a random effects model <strong>in</strong> which the correlation of the <strong>in</strong>dividual effect and the<strong>in</strong>itial condition is unspecified.6 A further argument is that <strong>in</strong> a mult<strong>in</strong>omial framework random effects specification requires<strong>in</strong>tegration over multiple dimensions which is a major computational challenge.6


cont<strong>in</strong>uous explanatory variables the exact equality condition is replaced byweight<strong>in</strong>g the differences with a kernel function and giv<strong>in</strong>g the observationswith smallest differences the highest weights. The likelihood function <strong>for</strong> model(1) is given <strong>in</strong> the Appendix. The semi-parametric estimator converges to thetrue value at a speed slower than the standard √ N rate. In addition, due tothe use of the weight<strong>in</strong>g scheme only a smaller number of observations is used<strong>for</strong> maximization. There<strong>for</strong>e it is crucial that the estimation is based on a largesample.The method allows strictly exogenous variables x which are time vary<strong>in</strong>g butwith the support of x it − x is <strong>in</strong> the neighborhood of 0 <strong>for</strong> any t ≠ s. For thisreason time dummies are excluded. We model age effects on wage mobility bydef<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g dummy variables <strong>for</strong> age groups.For every contribution to the likelihood function the state at two different po<strong>in</strong>ts<strong>in</strong> time, the state <strong>in</strong> the periods be<strong>for</strong>e and afterwards and the values of the<strong>in</strong>dependent variables at these dates are important. There<strong>for</strong>e the method canbe <strong>in</strong>terpreted as collect<strong>in</strong>g similar histories of states and covariates, whichmake similar contributions to the likelihood. In contrast the estimation ofthe mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit, model (3), corresponds to the estimation of the pooleddata, neglect<strong>in</strong>g the panel structure or <strong>in</strong>dividual histories. This estimatoralso assumes that the <strong>in</strong>itial states are exogenously given, which is less of arestriction once we assume there are no <strong>in</strong>dividual effects.4 DataIn <strong>Austria</strong> the social security authority collects detailed <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation <strong>for</strong> allworkers, except <strong>for</strong> self-employed, civil servants and marg<strong>in</strong>al workers. We usea random sample drawn from these adm<strong>in</strong>istrative records. The data conta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation on wages and labor market status of the <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>for</strong> every dayand cover the years 1986 to 1998.There are major advantages of us<strong>in</strong>g adm<strong>in</strong>istrative data compared to the analyzesbased on surveys. First, there is no outflow apart from death and migrationand <strong>in</strong>flow <strong>in</strong>to the sample is random. Hence sample attrition, whichis often considerable <strong>in</strong> longitud<strong>in</strong>al surveys, is not an issue <strong>in</strong> adm<strong>in</strong>istrativedata. Second, the measurement of <strong>in</strong>dividual wages is highly reliable, which isextremely important <strong>for</strong> analyz<strong>in</strong>g longitud<strong>in</strong>al wage development. F<strong>in</strong>ally, thesample size is very large, which is crucial <strong>for</strong> the chosen estimation method.The total sample conta<strong>in</strong>s daily <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation on about 73,000 persons, who have7


een <strong>in</strong> the labor <strong>for</strong>ce at least <strong>for</strong> one day between 1986 and 1998.As the data are collected <strong>for</strong> social security reasons there are several shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs<strong>for</strong> empirical analysis. Earn<strong>in</strong>gs data are top censored because of thecontribution assessment ceil<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the social security system. The sample weuse <strong>for</strong> the analysis conta<strong>in</strong>s at most 15% censored wage observation per year.We avoid problems with top censor<strong>in</strong>g by analyz<strong>in</strong>g wage qu<strong>in</strong>tiles.Further, thenumber of observable worker characteristics is rather scarce. Especially, we haveno <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation on school<strong>in</strong>g and work<strong>in</strong>g time. In our analysis wage mobilityis exam<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> terms of monthly earn<strong>in</strong>gs. The lack of <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation on work<strong>in</strong>gtime is important ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>for</strong> women, as part-time work is quite unusual <strong>for</strong> men<strong>in</strong> <strong>Austria</strong>. 7As a measure <strong>for</strong> <strong>in</strong>come we use the gross monthly wage on May 31st of eachyear. <strong>Wage</strong>s are categorized accord<strong>in</strong>g to the qu<strong>in</strong>tiles of the yearly wage distribution.Individuals with zero wage <strong>in</strong>come on May 31st fall <strong>in</strong>to the categorynon-employed.We exclude all <strong>in</strong>dividuals from the sample who have zero earn<strong>in</strong>gs throughoutthe whole period and who are younger than 16 <strong>in</strong> 1998 and older than 64 <strong>in</strong> 1986.We are only <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> analyz<strong>in</strong>g movements with<strong>in</strong> the wage distribution.Transitions from education <strong>in</strong>to the labor <strong>for</strong>ce or transitions to retirementshould there<strong>for</strong>e be not considered. 8 The reductions leave an unbalanced panelof 43,078 (18,422 female) workers.To control <strong>for</strong> macro economic effects we <strong>in</strong>clude the unemployment rate ata regional level as an explanatory variable <strong>in</strong> the model.We use the averageunemployment rate dur<strong>in</strong>g the second quarter of each year <strong>for</strong> 120 politicaldistricts. 9The choice of the other explanatory variables is motivated by theresults <strong>in</strong> ?. Young <strong>in</strong>dividuals and <strong>in</strong>dividuals who changed their employerwere found to be the most mobile, whereas other population groups displayedonly m<strong>in</strong>or differences <strong>in</strong> wage mobility. Hence we are <strong>in</strong>terested to study theeffects of age (especially young age) and employer changes on wage mobility.We <strong>in</strong>clude age effects <strong>in</strong> the model by def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g dummy variables <strong>for</strong> 3 five-yearage groups between the ages of 20 and 35.The effects of employer changesare measured by aggregat<strong>in</strong>g the number of different employers over the years.7 The share of part-time work 1990 was 20% <strong>for</strong> women and 1.5% <strong>for</strong> men; it was ris<strong>in</strong>gdur<strong>in</strong>g the 1990’s.8 For any <strong>in</strong>dividual over the age of 55 we def<strong>in</strong>e a series of observations <strong>in</strong> state nonemploymentwhich reaches the end year 1998 as retirement. Analogously <strong>for</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dividualunder the age 27 we def<strong>in</strong>e a series of non-employment observations which starts <strong>in</strong> the firstyear (1986) as education. Those observations are excluded from the estimation.9 We thank Alfred Stigelbauer <strong>for</strong> provid<strong>in</strong>g the unemployment rates.8


There may be problems with the assumption of strict exogeneity of the numberof employers <strong>in</strong> the dynamic model, however. An unsatisfactory <strong>in</strong>comesituation might <strong>in</strong>duce the <strong>in</strong>dividual to look <strong>for</strong> a better job and change theemployer. This means there could be feedback effects from the lagged dependentvariable on the number of employers. ? and ? estimate models allow<strong>in</strong>g<strong>for</strong> feedback effects us<strong>in</strong>g a random effects specification. No such alternative isavailable <strong>for</strong> the fixed effects model. We alternatively estimate a specificationomitt<strong>in</strong>g the number of employers variable. The ma<strong>in</strong> results do not change, sowe leave the variable <strong>in</strong> the model <strong>for</strong> the results presented here.A list of descriptive statistics is given <strong>in</strong> Table 1. We notice that the distributionamong wage qu<strong>in</strong>tiles is different <strong>for</strong> men and women. Men are rather to befound <strong>in</strong> the upper part of the wage distribution. In the top qu<strong>in</strong>tile we f<strong>in</strong>d24% of all male observations but only 7% females. The picture is reversedat the bottom, where women are dom<strong>in</strong>ant. This could also be an effect ofthe <strong>in</strong>clusion of part-time work<strong>in</strong>g women <strong>in</strong> the sample. A matrix of yearlytransitions between wage categories is given <strong>in</strong> Table 2. Persistence seems tobe highest <strong>in</strong> the top qu<strong>in</strong>tile <strong>for</strong> both sexes. Men, however, move out of thebottom wage qu<strong>in</strong>tiles more quickly than women.5 ResultsIn this section we contrast the estimation results from the model controll<strong>in</strong>g<strong>for</strong> unobserved heterogeneity (1) with the mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit model (2) to seewhether there is spurious state dependence. For the apparent differences betweenthe sexes we conduct all estimations separately <strong>for</strong> men and women andcompare the results. Further we analyze the <strong>in</strong>fluence of the explanatory variableson wage mobility.The fixed effects estimation does not allow to estimate marg<strong>in</strong>al effects and toquantify the effects. We can only <strong>in</strong>terprete the signs of the estimated parametersand compare the relative magnitudes of parameters between the models.One way of measur<strong>in</strong>g wage mobility would be to look at persistence, e.g. theprobability to stay <strong>in</strong> the current state. We <strong>in</strong>vestigate how the degree of persistencechanges from a model not controll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>for</strong> any heterogeneity (3) to themodel controll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>for</strong> observed heterogeneity only (2), and <strong>in</strong> the model controll<strong>in</strong>g<strong>for</strong> both observed and unobserved heterogeneity (1). In the latter model wecannot give an exact measure of persistence but we calculate an upper bound.In this way we are able to quantify the effect of spurious state dependencerelative to genu<strong>in</strong>e state dependence on wage mobility.9


Another possibility to compare the relative importance of the effects and thedifferences between women and men is by simulat<strong>in</strong>g wage profiles. This is whatwe do <strong>in</strong> the last part of this section.5.1 Estimated parametersEstimation results of the model controll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>for</strong> unobserved heterogeneity (1)are given <strong>for</strong> women and men <strong>in</strong> Tables 3 and 4. Results from estimation ofthe mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit model (2) with no unobserved heterogeneity are given<strong>in</strong> Tables 5 and 6. In each model we choose non-employment as the referencestate.First, let us compare the feedback parameters γ <strong>in</strong> models (1) and (2). Theelements on the diagonal as well as on the upper and lower diagonal are larger<strong>in</strong> model (2) not controll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>for</strong> unobserved heterogeneity <strong>for</strong> both, men andwomen. On the other hand, the elements <strong>in</strong> the corners of the matrix are higher<strong>in</strong> this model whenever they are significantly different from zero. Thus, <strong>in</strong>deed,mobility is underestimated if we do not take spurious state dependence <strong>in</strong>toaccount.A <strong>for</strong>mal test <strong>for</strong> the hypothesis that there is no unobserved heterogeneitycan be constructed as a Hausman test. Tables 5 and 6 present consistent andefficient estimates under the null hypothesis and estimates <strong>in</strong> Tables 3 and 4 areconsistent under the null and the alternative. The null hypothesis is stronglyrejected. The test statistic is equal to 56,099 <strong>for</strong> female results (61,900 <strong>for</strong> maleresults) and is under the null hypothesis distributed as χ 2 (45).After thus reject<strong>in</strong>g the mult<strong>in</strong>omial model (2) we go on to discuss the differencebetween women and men <strong>in</strong> model (1), look<strong>in</strong>g at Tables 3 and 4. In both casesthe γ parameters take on higher values above the diagonal, than below. Thiswould imply a tendency to move upwards <strong>in</strong> the wage distribution. Womenhave higher probability to move to any position <strong>in</strong> the wage distribution thanto move to non-employment if they are currently <strong>in</strong> the lower qu<strong>in</strong>tiles. Thiscan be seen from the coefficients <strong>in</strong> the first two rows of the γ matrix, whichare higher <strong>for</strong> women than <strong>for</strong> men. Women start<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the upper qu<strong>in</strong>tiles,however, have a lower probability to stay <strong>in</strong> paid employment than men.Next, we turn to the effects of the covariates on wage mobility. As expectedhigher regional unemployment rate has a negative effect on the probability tomove to any qu<strong>in</strong>tile relative to mov<strong>in</strong>g to non-employment. For men theseeffects are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g with wage qu<strong>in</strong>tiles, with the more negative effects <strong>in</strong> theupper qu<strong>in</strong>tiles. For women, the unemployment only plays a significant role10


<strong>in</strong> the first and second qu<strong>in</strong>tiles. An employer change raises the probability ofmov<strong>in</strong>g to each wage qu<strong>in</strong>tile as compared to mov<strong>in</strong>g to non-employment. Aga<strong>in</strong>the effects are different <strong>for</strong> men and women. For women the effect of employerchange seems to be stable across qu<strong>in</strong>tiles, which would mean that chang<strong>in</strong>gthe employer does not contribute to upward movement <strong>in</strong> the distribution. Formen, the coefficient estimates are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g and chang<strong>in</strong>g the employer helpsthem to move to higher <strong>in</strong>come states. (Note, problems with strict exogeneityof this variable.)We also estimate the effects of three age groups (< 25 years, 25 to 29 years and30 to 34 years) as we assume that higher aged <strong>in</strong>dividuals show less mobilitythan young ones. Indeed the parameter estimates are highest <strong>for</strong> the youngestgroup, who are most likely to move to any qu<strong>in</strong>tile compared to mov<strong>in</strong>g to nonemploymentboth <strong>for</strong> men and <strong>for</strong> women. For all age groups it is most likelyto move to the bottom wage qu<strong>in</strong>tile, but the differences among parameters <strong>for</strong>the different qu<strong>in</strong>tiles are highest <strong>for</strong> the youngest <strong>in</strong>dividuals.5.2 Persistence measuresThe aim is to def<strong>in</strong>e a measure of persistency and compare the measure <strong>for</strong> threemodels: the model with no heterogeneity (3), the model with only observedheterogeneity (2) and the model with observed and unobserved heterogeneity(1). The measure of persistency will be reduced when we control <strong>for</strong> all sourcesof <strong>in</strong>dividual heterogeneity. In the third model it should only measure thedegree of genu<strong>in</strong>e state dependence.We def<strong>in</strong>e a measure of persistence by the sum of average probabilities of stay<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> each stateM(x, α) = 1 nn∑ 5∑P (y it = k|y i,t−1 = k, x i , α i )i=1 k=0In <strong>in</strong> model (3), the probabilities are constant <strong>for</strong> all <strong>in</strong>dividuals and F is simplygiven by the sum of the diagonal elements <strong>in</strong> the transition matrix (Table 2). Inmodel (2), estimated by the pooled mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit, we average the predictedprobabilities <strong>for</strong> stay<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> each state over all <strong>in</strong>dividualsIn model (1) th<strong>in</strong>gs are more complicated. As we do not have consistent estimates<strong>for</strong> the α i we cannot calculate predicted probabilities. We can, however,give an upper bound <strong>for</strong> the persistence measure F by select<strong>in</strong>g α such that <strong>for</strong>every <strong>in</strong>dividual the persistence <strong>for</strong> the predicted probabilities from the fixed11


effects logit model is maximized.M(x, α ∗ ) = maxα1nn∑i=1 k=05∑P (y it = k|y i,t−1 = k, x i , α i )The maximum value of the objective function is <strong>in</strong>dependent of x so it is sufficientto f<strong>in</strong>d α ∗ <strong>for</strong> a s<strong>in</strong>gle value of x. We need not per<strong>for</strong>m the maximization<strong>for</strong> all possible comb<strong>in</strong>ations of x values.Further, the objective function isnot strictly concave. It is not possible to give an analytical expression <strong>for</strong> themaximum. We found the maximum value by numerical methods.Table 7 gives the persistence measures <strong>for</strong> women and men <strong>in</strong> all three models.We see that only controll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>for</strong> observed heterogeneity does not reduce themeasure a lot. This may be, because we only have a limited number of personalcharacteristics available. The upper bound of the persistence measure of model(1), however is considerably smaller. Controll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>for</strong> unobserved heterogeneityat least reduces persistence by 27% <strong>for</strong> women (28% <strong>for</strong> men). For comparison,<strong>in</strong> the random effects model ?f<strong>in</strong>d that heterogeneity expla<strong>in</strong>s about50% to 70% of the overall persistence <strong>in</strong> welfare and labor <strong>for</strong>ce participation,respectively.5.3 SimulationsThe <strong>in</strong>terpretation of the transition parameters <strong>in</strong> the mult<strong>in</strong>omial model iscomplicated by the large number of parameters and the condition<strong>in</strong>g on referencestate and the unobserved fixed effects. Also as discussed be<strong>for</strong>e themagnitude of the s<strong>in</strong>gle effects cannot be quantified. Here we use a simulationapproach: we design artificial <strong>in</strong>dividuals with special unobserved and observedcharacteristics and plot their simulated earn<strong>in</strong>gs profiles. This will enable us tosee whether the <strong>in</strong>terpretations we gave above to the parameter estimates showup <strong>in</strong> earn<strong>in</strong>gs profiles and which are the more important and less importanteffects.We beg<strong>in</strong> with choos<strong>in</strong>g the unobserved propensity of be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> each qu<strong>in</strong>tilewith respect to non-employment α = (α 1 , . . . , α 5 ). We consider one <strong>in</strong>dividualwith high propensity to move up <strong>in</strong> the wage distribution (where α 1 is smallcompared to α 5 ), one with high propensity <strong>for</strong> the lower part of the distribution(where α 1 is large compared to α 5 ) and one who is <strong>in</strong>different between the wagequ<strong>in</strong>tiles (α 1 = . . . = α 1 ). 10 For these <strong>in</strong>dividuals we choose 3 different start<strong>in</strong>g10 The constant term estimates <strong>in</strong> the mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit model give an approximation <strong>for</strong>12


ages (20 years, 30 years and over 35 years) and employer careers (the sameemployer over the total period employer changes every two years). For each<strong>in</strong>dividual female and male profiles are contrasted. The unemployment rate isassumed constant <strong>for</strong> all cases.We generate earn<strong>in</strong>gs profiles by calculat<strong>in</strong>g the probability distribution overstates <strong>in</strong> each year and choos<strong>in</strong>g the state nearest to the expected value asthe state of the current year. In period T = 0 all <strong>in</strong>dividuals start at qu<strong>in</strong>tile1, to display a maximum of movements <strong>in</strong> the profiles. This process is runiteratively over 15 years and the result<strong>in</strong>g earn<strong>in</strong>gs profiles are displayed graphically<strong>in</strong> Figures 1 to 3. We use the mean from the unconditional distribution(the equilibrium distribution of the <strong>Markov</strong> process) as a benchmark state. Ifthe <strong>in</strong>dividual starts her earn<strong>in</strong>gs career at the bottom of the distribution thepersistence parameters will determ<strong>in</strong>e if or how fast she is able to reach theunconditional mean state over time. 11It should be stressed that this method cannot give evidence <strong>for</strong> the developmentof earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>for</strong> some representative <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong> the sample, as the values <strong>for</strong>α are taken ad hoc. The only use of the graphical results is <strong>in</strong> simplify<strong>in</strong>g the<strong>in</strong>terpretation of the estimated parameters.Figure 1 shows earn<strong>in</strong>gs profiles <strong>for</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dividual with low propensity of mov<strong>in</strong>gto the upper wage qu<strong>in</strong>tile, α is set to −(1, 1.5, 2, 2.5, 3). The pictures on theleft show women with different ages <strong>in</strong> the start<strong>in</strong>g year. Male equivalents areshown on the right hand side. An <strong>in</strong>dividual never chang<strong>in</strong>g their employer ofeither sex and age group rema<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> the first qu<strong>in</strong>tile <strong>for</strong> the whole period. Itakes them longer than 15 years to reach their mean <strong>in</strong>come state (qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2).The man’s upward movement can however be achieved by employer change. 12For those men we also observe an age effect: older men mov<strong>in</strong>g sooner.Next, Figure 2 with <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>in</strong>different between qu<strong>in</strong>tiles <strong>in</strong> the wage distribution(α = −(1, 1, 1, 1, 1)) shows more mobility already. The unconditionalmean positions shift to wage qu<strong>in</strong>tiles three to five.Men move quicker andfarther <strong>in</strong> the wage distribution. The youngest man reaches the unconditionalthe magnitude of the chosen α values.11 For a first order <strong>Markov</strong> process the equilibrium or unconditional probability distributioncan be calculated from the matrix of transition probabilities. It is given by the eigenvector tothe eigenvalue one, normalized to the length of one. The equilibrium probability distributionthen determ<strong>in</strong>es the unconditional mean state <strong>for</strong> every <strong>in</strong>dividual. If we let the <strong>in</strong>dividualstart at the mean state and do not change its observed characteristics the <strong>in</strong>dividual willrema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> this state <strong>for</strong>ever.12 Employer changes every two years are a very dynamic scenario. The average number ofemployer changes per <strong>in</strong>dividual over twelve years is two <strong>in</strong> the sample, only one per cent of<strong>in</strong>dividuals changes their employer more than five times.13


mean after seven years. Aga<strong>in</strong> men profit a lot from employer changes.The most <strong>for</strong>tunate <strong>in</strong>dividuals are shown <strong>in</strong> Figure 3, with α = −(3, 2.5, 2, 1.5, 1).We now observe everyone to move out of the bottom wage qu<strong>in</strong>tile after oneyear and most of them reach their mean state with<strong>in</strong> a few periods. Men movefaster and further even without employer changes.Overall the simulations confirm the <strong>in</strong>terpretation of a tendency towards upwardmovements <strong>in</strong> the wage distribution. Only men are supported by employerchanges. Older <strong>in</strong>dividuals move higher <strong>in</strong> the distribution. Men are moremobile than women.6 ConclusionThis study has <strong>in</strong>vestigated wage mobility <strong>in</strong> terms of transitions between qu<strong>in</strong>tilesof the wage distribution. We have modeled <strong>in</strong>dividual transitions as a firstorder <strong>Markov</strong> process with heterogeneous <strong>in</strong>dividuals. In the model we controlled<strong>for</strong> macroeconomic <strong>in</strong>fluences via the regional unemployment rate, ageeffects, and the effects of employer changes. In addition, we allowed <strong>for</strong> unobserved<strong>in</strong>dividual effects to capture spurious state dependence. The chosenestimation method is a dynamic mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit framework with fixed effectsbased on conditional likelihood maximization (?). With this method we canconsistently estimate the model parameters although we leave the distributionof the <strong>in</strong>dividual effects as well as the correlation between the <strong>in</strong>dividual effects,the <strong>in</strong>itial state, and exogenous variables completely unspecified. For the empiricalanalysis we have used data from <strong>Austria</strong>n adm<strong>in</strong>istrative sources, whichhave the advantage of provid<strong>in</strong>g highly accurate wage <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation <strong>for</strong> a largenumber of <strong>in</strong>dividuals over a long time period.The results confirm that it is important to control <strong>for</strong> spurious state dependence.A model controll<strong>in</strong>g only <strong>for</strong> observed heterogeneity is strongly rejected aga<strong>in</strong>stthe more general specification. Thus, wage mobility is underestimated if we donot take spurious state dependence <strong>in</strong>to account. In the case of the <strong>Austria</strong>neconomy with a very rigid wage sett<strong>in</strong>g system ? found that wage mobilityis extremely low <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational comparison. Our results show that about70% of the aggregate persistence <strong>in</strong> wages are due to true state dependence.Hence the centralized wage barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g scheme seems to contribute to wagepersistence to a large amount. On the other hand, a share of at least 30% <strong>in</strong>the persistence stems from <strong>in</strong>dividual heterogeneity. This means that <strong>in</strong>dividualeffects certa<strong>in</strong>ly should not be neglected when measur<strong>in</strong>g wage mobility.14


The exam<strong>in</strong>ation of simulated wage profiles shows that women are less mobilethan men. This is especially disturb<strong>in</strong>g as women tend to rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> the lowerpart of the wage distribution. Our results give the impression that, even conditionalon <strong>in</strong>dividual heterogeneity, there exist huge barriers <strong>for</strong> women to moveout of the lower part of the wage distribution.There are several ways <strong>in</strong> which the research issues <strong>in</strong> this paper can be extended.There are arguments that the large effects of unobserved heterogeneityon transition parameters may be due to heterogeneity of transitions themselvesbetween <strong>in</strong>dividuals. Mean<strong>in</strong>g that the dynamics of the <strong>Markov</strong> process arehigher than one. To the best of our knowledge <strong>for</strong> the mult<strong>in</strong>omial model thereexist neither Monte Carlo simulations <strong>for</strong> the convergence properties of the estimationmethod, sensitivity of the method to model misspecification and comparisonof alternative estimation methodologies (fixed effects, random effects).This would of course complement our <strong>in</strong>vestigation of wage mobility.ReferencesAbowd, J. M. and Card, D. (1998). On the covariance structure of earn<strong>in</strong>gsand hours changes. Econometrica, 57:411–445.Alvarez, J., Brown<strong>in</strong>g, M., and Ejrnaes, M. (2002). <strong>Model</strong>l<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>come processeswith lots of heterogeneity. Paper presented at the 10th InternationalConference on Panel Data. Berl<strong>in</strong>.Baker, M. (1997). Growth-rate heterogeneity and covariance structure of lifecycleearn<strong>in</strong>gs. Journal of Labor Economics, 15:338–375.Baker, M. and Solon, G. (2003). Earn<strong>in</strong>gs dynamics and <strong>in</strong>equality amongCanadian men, 1972-1992: evidence from longitud<strong>in</strong>al tax records. Journalof Labor Economics, 21:389–321.Biewen, M. (2004). Measur<strong>in</strong>g state dependence <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual poverty status:are there feedback effects to employement decisions and household composition?IZA Discussion Paper, (1138). Bonn.Bonhomme, S. and Rob<strong>in</strong>, J.-M. (2004). <strong>Model</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividual earn<strong>in</strong>gs trajectoriesus<strong>in</strong>g copulas with an application to the study of earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong>equality.Paper presented at the 18th Annual Conference of the European Society <strong>for</strong>Population Economics. Bergen.15


Buch<strong>in</strong>sky, M., Fields, G. S., Fougére, D., and Kramarz, F. (2003). Francs orranks? Earn<strong>in</strong>gs mobility <strong>in</strong> France, 1967-1999. CEPR Discussion Papers,(3937).Cappellari, L. and Jenk<strong>in</strong>s, S. P. (2004). <strong>Model</strong>l<strong>in</strong>g low <strong>in</strong>come transitions.Journal of Applied Econometrics. <strong>for</strong>thcom<strong>in</strong>g.Chamberla<strong>in</strong>, G. (1984). Panel data. In Grilliches, Z. and Intriligator, M.,editors, Handbook of Econometrics, volume 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam.Chay, K. Y. and Hyslop, D. R. (2004). Identification and estimation of dynamicb<strong>in</strong>ary response panel data models: empirical evidence us<strong>in</strong>g alternative approaches.Journal of Econometrics. <strong>for</strong>thcom<strong>in</strong>g.Ch<strong>in</strong>tagunta, P., Kyriazidou, E., and Perktold, J. (2001). Panel data analysisof household brand choices. Journal of Econometrics, 103:111–153.Dickens, R. (2000). The evolution of <strong>in</strong>dividual earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> Great Brita<strong>in</strong>:1975-95. The Economic Journal, 110:27–49.Fields, G. S. and Ok, E. A. (1999). The measurement of <strong>in</strong>come mobility:an <strong>in</strong>troduction to the literature. In Silber, J., editor, Handbook of <strong>in</strong>come<strong>in</strong>equality measurement. Kluwer Academic Publishers, New York.Geweke, J. and Keane, M. (2000). An empirical analysis of earn<strong>in</strong>gs dynamicsamong men <strong>in</strong> the PSID: 1968-1989. Journal of Econometrics, 96:293–356.Heckman, J. J. (1981a). The <strong>in</strong>cidental parameters problem and the problemof <strong>in</strong>itial conditions <strong>in</strong> estimat<strong>in</strong>g a discrete time-discrete data stochasticprocess. In Manski, C. F. and McFadden, D., editors, Structural analysis ofdiscrete data with econometric applications, chapter 4. MIT Press, CambridgeMassachusetts.Heckman, J. J. (1981b). Statistical models <strong>for</strong> discrete panel data. In Manski,C. F. and McFadden, D., editors, Structural analysis of discrete data witheconometric applications, chapter 3. MIT Press, Cambridge Massachusetts.Hofer, H. and Weber, A. (2002). <strong>Wage</strong> mobility <strong>in</strong> <strong>Austria</strong> 1986 - 1996. LabourEconomics, 9:563–577.Honoré, B. E. (2002). Nonl<strong>in</strong>ear models with panel data. Portuguese EconomicJournal, 1:163–179.Honoré, B. E. and Kyriazidou, E. (2000). Panel data discrete choice modelswith lagged dependent variables. Econometrica, 68:839–874.16


Honoré, B. E. and Tamer, E. (2004). Bounds on parameters <strong>in</strong> dynamic discretechoice models. Paper presented at the 11th International Conference on PanelData. Texas A&M.Hu, L. (2002). Estimation of a dynamic censored panel data model. Econometrica,70:2499–2517.Magnac, T. (2000). Subsidised tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and youth employment: dist<strong>in</strong>guish<strong>in</strong>gunobserved heterogeneity from state dependence <strong>in</strong> labour market histories.The Economic Journal, 110:805–837.McCall, J. J. (1971). A <strong>Markov</strong>ian model of <strong>in</strong>come dynamics. Journal of theAmerican Statistical Association, 66:439–447.McFadden, D. (1974). Conditional logit anaysis of qualitative choice behaviour.In Zarembka, P., editor, Frontiers <strong>in</strong> Econometrics. Academic Press, NewYork.Meghir, C. and Pistaferri, L. (2004). Income variance dynamics and heterogeneity.Econometrica, 72:1–32.Shorrocks, A. F. (1978a). Income <strong>in</strong>equality and <strong>in</strong>come mobility. Journal ofEconomic Theory, 19:376–393.Shorrocks, A. F. (1978b). The measurement of mobility. Econometrica, 46:1013–1024.Wooldridge, J. (2000). A framework <strong>for</strong> estimat<strong>in</strong>g dynamic, unobserved effectspanel data models with possible feedback to future explanatory variables.Economics Letters, 68:245–250.Wooldridge, J. (2004). Simple solutions to the <strong>in</strong>itial conditions problem <strong>in</strong>dynamic nonl<strong>in</strong>ear panel data models with unobserved heterogeneity. Journalof Applied Econometrics. <strong>for</strong>thcom<strong>in</strong>g.17


Appendix: Likelihood function <strong>for</strong> the dynamic mult<strong>in</strong>omiallogit model with fixed effectsDef<strong>in</strong>e the b<strong>in</strong>ary variable y hit = 1 if the <strong>in</strong>dividual i is <strong>in</strong> state h ∈ {0, 1, . . . , m}<strong>in</strong> period t and zero otherwise. The estimation of model (1) with person specific<strong>in</strong>dividual characteristics x it and fixed <strong>in</strong>dividual effects α ki can be based onthe maximization of the follow<strong>in</strong>g likelihood function:L =+N∑∑i=1 1≤t


Table 1: Descriptive StatisticsWomenMenMean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev.No <strong>in</strong>come 0.241 0.160Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 0.293 0.055Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 0.184 0.138Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 0.119 0.195Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 0.097 0.214Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5 0.067 0.237Observations 199,932 273,323Number of employers 1.93 1.23 2.15 1.47Age (years) 31.91 12.74 32.89 12.62Age < 25 0.34 0.47 0.30 0.46Age 25 to 29 0.13 0.33 0.15 0.36Age 30 to 34 0.12 0.33 0.12 0.32Mean unemployment rates1987 5.52 1.91 5.60 1.951998 4.24 1.77 4.45 1.69Individuals 20,897 27,826NOTE: Age of <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong> 1987Cumulative number of employers <strong>in</strong> 199820


Table 2: Estimated transition probabilities, yearly transitions 1986-1998, noheterogeneityWomenDest<strong>in</strong>ation state No <strong>in</strong>come Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5Orig<strong>in</strong> stateNo <strong>in</strong>come 0.760 0.156 0.047 0.020 0.012 0.005Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 0.108 0.796 0.080 0.011 0.005 0.001Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 0.081 0.068 0.741 0.100 0.008 0.001Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 0.064 0.012 0.078 0.728 0.114 0.003Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 0.056 0.005 0.008 0.064 0.790 0.076Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5 0.044 0.002 0.001 0.004 0.048 0.899MenDest<strong>in</strong>ation State No Income Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5Orig<strong>in</strong> stateNo <strong>in</strong>come 0.728 0.068 0.088 0.057 0.036 0.023Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 0.176 0.610 0.155 0.038 0.015 0.006Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 0.096 0.039 0.662 0.177 0.023 0.003Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 0.053 0.008 0.086 0.704 0.145 0.005Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 0.036 0.003 0.010 0.091 0.767 0.093Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5 0.025 0.002 0.002 0.004 0.055 0.913NOTE: number of observations 199,932 females; 273,323 males. number of <strong>in</strong>dividuals20,897 females; 27,826 males21


Table 3: Estimated parameters from transition model with observed and unobservedheterogeneity, Women, yearly transitions 1986-1998Dest<strong>in</strong>ation State Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5Orig<strong>in</strong> stateQu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 3.264 2.73 1.925 1.625 0.998(0.085) (0.106) (0.181) (0.293) (0.574)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 1.8 3.892 3.369 2.323 1.915(0.103) (0.112) (0.141) (0.248) (0.574)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 0.392 2.219 4.051 3.545 2.26(0.204) (0.133) (0.150) (0.192) (0.371)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 -0.681 0.552 2.582 4.51 3.593(0.346) (0.250) (0.169) (0.200) (0.266)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5 0.065 -0.825 0.358 2.623 4.454(0.642) (0.723) (0.519) (0.258) (0.305)Regional unemployment rate -0.084 -0.115 -0.053 -0.088 -0.072(0.033) (0.035) (0.050) (0.061) (0.085)Number of employers 3.291 3.322 3.277 3.134 3.32(0.120) (0.132) (0.174) (0.211) (0.299)Age < 25 2.018 1.77 1.206 -0.124 0.203(0.374) (0.455) (0.529) (0.644) (1.069)Age 25 to 29 0.551 0.301 0.074 -0.522 -1.212(0.286) (0.372) (0.439) (0.490) (0.777)Age 30 to 34 0.196 -0.278 -0.191 -0.694 -1.143(0.209) (0.265) (0.319) (0.372) (0.488)number of cases 41890number of <strong>in</strong>dividuals 16841mean log Likelihood -0.174NOTE: fixed effects logit model estimated with conditional ML, Epanichnikov Kernelwith bandwidth 0.4, standard errors are <strong>in</strong> parentheses.22


Table 4: Estimated parameters from transition model with unobserved heterogeneity,Men, yearly transitions 1986-1998Dest<strong>in</strong>ation State Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5Orig<strong>in</strong> stateQu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 2.808 1.855 1.264 0.172 0.015(0.123) (0.123) (0.180) (0.304) (0.523)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 1.398 2.921 2.77 1.688 0.946(0.127) (0.097) (0.105) (0.161) (0.415)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 1.109 2.055 3.698 3.325 1.87(0.190) (0.106) (0.112) (0.125) (0.261)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 0.744 1.141 2.94 4.392 4.139(0.345) (0.165) (0.124) (0.135) (0.184)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5 0.503 0.693 1.767 3.233 5.079(0.458) (0.493) (0.235) (0.168) (0.209)Regional unemployment rate -0.079 -0.107 -0.122 -0.164 -0.123(0.040) (0.036) (0.035) (0.038) (0.048)Number of employers 2.736 3.231 3.272 3.365 3.601(0.138) (0.118) (0.123) (0.133) (0.162)Age < 25 2.471 1.757 1.144 1.054 0.101(0.516) (0.442) (0.441) (0.483) (0.604)Age 25 to 29 0.25 0.407 0.386 0.496 -0.035(0.390) (0.344) (0.337) (0.365) (0.434)Age 30 to 34 0.111 0.263 0.3 0.498 0.331(0.282) (0.250) (0.245) (0.266) (0.306)number of cases 47175number of <strong>in</strong>dividuals 21429mean log Likelihood -0.240NOTE: fixed effects logit model estimated with conditional ML, Epanichnikov Kernelwith bandwidth 0.4, standard errors are <strong>in</strong> parentheses.23


Table 5: Estimated parameters from pooled transition model (only observedheterogeneity), Women, yearly transitions 1986-1998Dest<strong>in</strong>ation State Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5Orig<strong>in</strong> stateQu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 3.590 2.436 1.298 0.966 0.238(0.019) (0.030) (0.053) (0.074) (0.149)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 1.409 4.956 3.803 1.749 0.887(0.030) (0.029) (0.042) (0.074) (0.154)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 -0.110 2.942 6.043 4.677 1.971(0.066) (0.041) (0.043) (0.053) (0.131)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 -0.854 0.780 3.729 6.720 5.137(0.105) (0.089) (0.054) (0.053) (0.075)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5 -1.475 -0.864 1.151 4.138 7.762(0.182) (0.247) (0.150) (0.073) (0.077)Regional unemployment rate -0.025 -0.065 -0.081 -0.100 -0.082(0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.007) (0.010)Number of employers 0.235 0.282 0.227 0.233 0.211(0.009) (0.011) (0.013) (0.016) (0.023)Age < 25 -0.807 -0.277 0.019 -0.051 -1.249(0.026) (0.030) (0.038) (0.056) (0.163)Age 25 to 29 -0.804 -0.602 -0.335 -0.256 -0.581(0.024) (0.028) (0.033) (0.040) (0.069)Age 30 to 34 -0.431 -0.486 -0.333 -0.286 -0.449(0.023) (0.028) (0.034) (0.040) (0.058)Constant -1.508 -2.626 -3.413 -3.825 -4.539(0.028) (0.037) (0.049) (0.061) (0.089)number of cases 199,932number of <strong>in</strong>dividuals 20,897mean log Likelihood -0.541NOTE: mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit estimation, T=12, the reference state is non-employment,standard errors are <strong>in</strong> parentheses.24


Table 6: Estimated parameters from pooled transition model (only observedheterogeneity), Men, yearly transitions 1986-1998Dest<strong>in</strong>ation State Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5Orig<strong>in</strong> stateQu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 3.641 1.950 0.991 0.514 0.171(0.030) (0.033) (0.049) (0.072) (0.106)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 1.479 4.008 3.143 1.568 0.045(0.036) (0.025) (0.030) (0.045) (0.098)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 0.462 2.600 5.143 4.016 1.148(0.056) (0.030) (0.029) (0.034) (0.071)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 -0.180 0.898 3.505 6.094 4.414(0.083) (0.050) (0.034) (0.035) (0.042)Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5 -0.481 -0.613 0.681 3.825 7.037(0.107) (0.104) (0.072) (0.041) (0.042)Regional unemployment rate 0.001 -0.005 -0.020 -0.040 -0.087(0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005)Number of employers 0.217 0.205 0.138 0.084 -0.003(0.010) (0.008) (0.008) (0.009) (0.011)Age < 25 -0.468 0.081 0.023 0.049 -0.400(0.037) (0.029) (0.030) (0.037) (0.067)Age 25 to 29 -0.206 0.116 0.101 0.243 0.199(0.033) (0.025) (0.024) (0.027) (0.036)Age 30 to 34 -0.176 -0.019 -0.048 0.036 0.049(0.031) (0.024) (0.024) (0.025) (0.031)Constant -2.651 -2.463 -2.685 -2.981 -2.998(0.040) (0.033) (0.034) (0.039) (0.048)number of cases 273,323number of <strong>in</strong>dividuals 27,826mean log Likelihood -0.523NOTE: mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit estimation ,T=12, the reference state is non-employment,standard errors are <strong>in</strong> parentheses.25


Table 7: Persistency measures accord<strong>in</strong>g to different models<strong>Model</strong> Women MenA: no heterogeneity 4.767 4.451B: observed heterogeneity 4.672 4.376C: observed and unobserved heterogeneity 3.488 3.212NOTE: Persistency is measured by the trace of the transition matrixresult<strong>in</strong>g from the esitmation of each model.For the model with oberved and unobserved heterogeneity an upperbound persistency measure is used.26


Figure 1: Simulated wage profiles α = −(1, 1.5, 2, 2.5, 3)27


Figure 2: Simulated wage profiles α = −(1, 1, 1, 1, 1)28


Figure 3: Simulated wage profiles α = −(3, 2.5, 2, 1.5, 1)29

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!