12.07.2015 Views

The logic of management consulting, parts 1 and 2

The logic of management consulting, parts 1 and 2

The logic of management consulting, parts 1 and 2

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Canback, Staffan. 1998. <strong>The</strong> Logic <strong>of</strong>Management Consulting, Part 1. Journal<strong>of</strong> Management Consulting 10 (2): 3-11A searchable text version <strong>of</strong> the article is found at the back <strong>of</strong> this document


THE LOGIC OFMANAGEMENTCONSULTINGPart OneStaffan Canback1998© 1998 Journal <strong>of</strong> Management ConsultingReprinted with permission from the Journal <strong>of</strong> Management Consulting


2Editor’s Note: In this the first <strong>of</strong> twoarticles in our series, “<strong>The</strong> Logic <strong>of</strong>Management Consulting,” StaffanCanback, a consultant at MonitorCompany, traces the history <strong>and</strong> trajectory<strong>of</strong> the <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>industry <strong>and</strong> introduces transactioncost theory. In the second articlein this series, Canback will usetransaction cost theory—originallydeveloped in the 1930s by Ronald H.Coase—to help explain the existence<strong>and</strong> phenomenal growth <strong>of</strong> this industry.Transaction cost theory has severalapplications in economics <strong>and</strong> <strong>management</strong>.One <strong>of</strong> the most importantis to help explain the boundaries <strong>of</strong>firms—why certain activities, products,or services are carried out internallyin firms—while others arebought <strong>and</strong> sold in the market place.As such it is a useful framework forthinking about <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>services. Why after all do executiveshire consultants when theymight do the work themselves?By using transaction cost theory asits intellectual foundation, the articleanswers two questions: 1) why do<strong>management</strong> consultants exist; <strong>and</strong>2) why do they organize in independentfirms?Despite current popularity <strong>and</strong> astoundinggrowth rates, <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> remains one <strong>of</strong> the leastresearched <strong>and</strong> written about industries(Gagnon 1984). We take forgranted that the industry should exist<strong>and</strong> function in the way it does. Yetthe tremendous growth <strong>of</strong> the <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> industry over thelast 20 years cannot be easily explained.As one “Bernie Ramsbottom”put it in the Financial Times(April 11, 1981):Of all the businesses, by farConsultancy’s the most bizarre.For to the penetrating eye,<strong>The</strong>re’s no apparent reason why,With no more assets than a pen,This group <strong>of</strong> personable menCan sell to clients more than twice<strong>The</strong> same ridiculous advice,Or find, in such a rich pr<strong>of</strong>usion,Problems to fit their own solution.For the purposes <strong>of</strong> this article, wewill define <strong>management</strong> consultantsas those who provide general <strong>management</strong>advice within a strategic,organizational or operational context,<strong>and</strong> who are institutionally organizedin firms. It excludes other types <strong>of</strong><strong>consulting</strong> such as human resource,information technology, <strong>and</strong> actuarial<strong>consulting</strong> which have little in commonwith <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>except for the project nature <strong>of</strong> work.It also excludes <strong>management</strong> consultantswho are not institutionally organized.My estimate is that the chosensegment <strong>of</strong> the <strong>consulting</strong> marketaccounts for around 30 to 40percent <strong>of</strong> total <strong>consulting</strong> revenues,<strong>and</strong> 80 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>revenues.What is <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>?According to Greiner <strong>and</strong> Metzger(1983): "<strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> isan advisory service contracted for<strong>and</strong> provided to organizations byspecially trained <strong>and</strong> qualified per-


3sons who assist, in an objective <strong>and</strong>independent manner, the client organizationto identify <strong>management</strong>problems, analyze such problems,recommend solutions to these problems,<strong>and</strong> help, when requested, inthe implementation <strong>of</strong> solutions."<strong>The</strong>re are a few key words in this definition.Advisory service indicatesthat the consultants are responsiblefor the quality <strong>of</strong> their advice, butthey do not substitute for managers<strong>and</strong> have no formal authority. Objective<strong>and</strong> independent indicates financial,administrative, political, <strong>and</strong>emotional independence from theclient (Kubr 1996). Trained <strong>and</strong> qualifiedshows that a consultant is morethan the individual <strong>and</strong> his or herpersonal experience. As we will see,these characteristics sometimes contributeto the dem<strong>and</strong> for external<strong>consulting</strong> services, <strong>and</strong> sometimesdetract from it.Within the context <strong>of</strong> the definitionabove, <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> hasa long history (e.g. Moore 1982;Kubr 1996; UNCTAD 1993). <strong>The</strong> first<strong>management</strong> consultants appearedaround the turn <strong>of</strong> the century <strong>and</strong>included individuals such as FrederickTaylor, Henry Gantt, Arthur D.Little, <strong>and</strong> Harrington Emerson, all <strong>of</strong>whom are still famous for their contributionsto the science <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong>.Little <strong>and</strong> Emerson alsostarted two <strong>of</strong> the first institutional<strong>consulting</strong> firms. <strong>The</strong>se pioneerswere mainly concerned with operationalefficiency issues such as Taylor'stime-<strong>and</strong>-motion theory.Between 1910 <strong>and</strong> 1940 a secondgeneration <strong>of</strong> consultants exp<strong>and</strong>edthe concept <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>.Edwin Booz started <strong>of</strong>fering"business research services" in1914, <strong>and</strong> James O. McKinseystarted McKinsey & Company in1926. In Europe, Lyndon Urwick <strong>and</strong>Charles Bedeaux were pioneers whocontributed extensively to defining<strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> in the1920s. <strong>The</strong>se consultants pioneeredor implemented techniques such asbudgeting processes, the divisionalizedorganization, merit-based compensationschemes, <strong>and</strong> forecastingtechniques.During the early post-war years <strong>and</strong>in many cases growing out <strong>of</strong> wartimeexperience, <strong>consulting</strong> experienceda big surge, with formation <strong>of</strong>such firms as Cresap, McCormick &Paget, William E. Hill, Bruce Payne &Associates, Hay Associates, <strong>and</strong>Towers Perrin.Three major developments tookplace in the 1960s. First, Bruce Hendersonmoved from Arthur D. Little,Inc. to start the Boston ConsultingGroup in 1963 <strong>and</strong> more or less single-h<strong>and</strong>edlyoperationalized theconcepts <strong>of</strong> strategy <strong>and</strong> strategy<strong>consulting</strong>. Out <strong>of</strong> this sprang asecond generation <strong>of</strong> strategy specialistssuch as Bain & Company,Strategic Planning Associates, BraxtonAssociates, LEK Partnership,<strong>and</strong> Monitor Company. Second, themajor accounting firms started respondingto the growth <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> <strong>and</strong> created <strong>management</strong>advisory service groups to


4augment their core accounting practices.Today the <strong>consulting</strong> practices<strong>of</strong> Andersen Worldwide, PricewaterhouseCoopers,Deloitte & Touche,<strong>and</strong> Ernst & Young <strong>of</strong>ten rival theaccounting activities <strong>of</strong> these firms insize.Also starting in the 1960s with theemergence <strong>of</strong> Cambridge ResearchInstitute <strong>and</strong> Management AnalysisCenter (today, both history), firmsinstitutionalizing the combined <strong>consulting</strong>practices <strong>of</strong> leading academics<strong>and</strong> practitioners began to maketheir presence known.Yet as late as 1980, despite a growingproliferation <strong>of</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> specialties,<strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> was stillan industry in its infancy with perhapsaround 18,000 practicing <strong>management</strong>consultants worldwide, <strong>and</strong>only around thirty to forty percent <strong>of</strong>these employed in the large, institutionallyorganized firms <strong>of</strong> the typementioned above 1 (ConsultantsNews 1982–1997; Payne 1986).Even the largest <strong>consulting</strong> firm inthose days, Booz•Allen & Hamilton,had revenues <strong>of</strong> only around $150million. <strong>The</strong> industry as a whole hadrevenues <strong>of</strong> $1.2 billion in the U.S.<strong>and</strong> worldwide perhaps $2 billion.Over the next 17 years, the <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> industry grew toaround $35 billion globally. <strong>The</strong> annualgrowth rate has been more than20 percent. Today, there are approx-1 <strong>The</strong> numbers presented in this section are theauthor’s reconciliation <strong>of</strong> several sources. <strong>The</strong>yare broadly in line with most observers.imately 140,000 consultants worldwide(a considerable fraction <strong>of</strong> thismore recent growth <strong>and</strong> peoplecount is accounted for by informationtechnology projects manned less by<strong>management</strong> consultants than bysystems integration specialists).This growth is impressive, but thetrue importance <strong>of</strong> the industry’s evolutionis the accumulation <strong>of</strong> institutionalknowledge. In 1980 there wereless than five <strong>consulting</strong> firms withmore than 1,000 consultants, todaythere are more than 30. If the experiencecurve applies in <strong>consulting</strong>services, then it may be noteworthythat approximately 80 percent <strong>of</strong> all<strong>consulting</strong> experience was generatedin the last 17 years, <strong>and</strong> only 20 percentin the period from 1886 (whenArthur D. Little started the first <strong>consulting</strong>firm) to 1980. As we will see,this has had pr<strong>of</strong>ound implicationsfor the division <strong>of</strong> labor <strong>and</strong> the balance<strong>of</strong> power between consultants<strong>and</strong> clients.MANAGEMENTCONSULTING'SIMPORTANCEMore than just a growth industry,<strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> in <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong>itself is one <strong>of</strong> the most important<strong>and</strong> enduring <strong>management</strong> techniquesdeveloped over the last 50years. A secondary effect <strong>of</strong> this inventionhas been the rapid dissemination<strong>of</strong> new frameworks, tools, <strong>and</strong>techniques in large companies.


5Surprisingly, however, not much hasbeen written about this phenomenon.In part, this must be because few areinterested in the topic—it is still seenas an admission <strong>of</strong> failure by manymanagers to use consultants, <strong>and</strong>who wants to read about failure? Inpart it is because the <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> firms are highly secretive,<strong>and</strong> thus difficult to analyze <strong>and</strong> underst<strong>and</strong>.A few facts <strong>and</strong> observations dospeak for themselves. Managementconsultants today employ around 25percent <strong>of</strong> the graduates from theleading business schools, <strong>and</strong> thosegraduates are usually among the topperformers in their class. Some traditionalcompanies have essentiallygiven up recruiting at these schoolssince <strong>consulting</strong> firms <strong>and</strong> investmentbanks can <strong>of</strong>fer what is perceivedas more career opportunity,better pay <strong>and</strong> a more stimulatingenvironment than traditional companiesin manufacturing or services.Another aspect is that today thereare approximately 70,000 <strong>management</strong>consultants in the UnitedStates, while there are around150,000 executives <strong>of</strong> the type consultantsnormally interact with atfirms governed through “complex”<strong>management</strong> (Granovetter 1984).That is, for each executive there are0.5 consultants who advise, full time.In 1980, this ratio was approximately0.1. Clearly, <strong>and</strong> without inferringany judgement on the relative contribution<strong>of</strong> executives <strong>and</strong> consultants,the balance <strong>of</strong> influence is shiftingdramatically.Finally, several industry observers,including Payne (1986), argue thatinnovation in fields such as strategyis dominated by <strong>management</strong> consultants,<strong>and</strong> not by managers oracademics. <strong>The</strong> same is probablytrue for other <strong>management</strong> disciplines.Take, for example, reengineeringin its various incarnations.Consequently, <strong>management</strong> consultantshave had a large impact on thestate <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong> due to both thequantity <strong>and</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> contributions.Yet, this does not explain why <strong>management</strong>consultants exist. It is notclear why managers would want togive away so much <strong>of</strong> their companies’intellectual agenda to outsiders.It is not obvious why it is more costeffective to hire experts from the outsidethan to do the same work internallyin companies. And even if it is,why is this happening on a massivescale now, <strong>and</strong> not 60 years ago?Why is it happening in the UnitedStates but only to a limited extent inJapan?Before addressing these issues, thenext three sections build a platform<strong>of</strong> underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the task <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong>consultants, <strong>and</strong> the basics<strong>of</strong> transaction cost theory, by reviewingthe relevant literature.


6MANAGEMENTCONSULTANTS’ ROLES ANDTASKSSchein (1988) categorizes <strong>management</strong>consultants with respect to therole they play in their interaction withclients. He distinguishes betweenthree models <strong>of</strong> consultation: 1) purchase<strong>of</strong> expertise; 2) doctor–patient,<strong>and</strong> 3) process consultation.<strong>The</strong> purchase <strong>of</strong> expertise model isused by clients who require the consultantto bring their own independentperspective on the industry <strong>and</strong>the issues at h<strong>and</strong>. In its purest form,the consultant is not expected to interactextensively with the client butrather to provide his or her expertisein a h<strong>and</strong>s-<strong>of</strong>f relationship.In the doctor–patient model, the consultantemphasizes his or her diagnosticcapability by carefully analyzingthe client organization’s problems.Using the consultant’s <strong>of</strong>tenunique experience base <strong>and</strong> diagnosticskill, the consultant quickly assessesstrategic <strong>and</strong> organizationalblockages. This model leads to anintimate <strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong>ten trust-based relationshipbetween the consultant <strong>and</strong>the client.<strong>The</strong> process consultation modelbuilds on the notion that the consultantis the facilitator, while the clientcontributes the expertise. Thus,there is a clear division <strong>of</strong> roles <strong>and</strong>tasks. <strong>The</strong> client ultimately chooseswhat to do about a problem. <strong>The</strong>consultant, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, providesa methodology for defining theproblem <strong>and</strong> finding the best possiblesolutions. <strong>The</strong> similarity to psycho<strong>logic</strong>alanalysis methods is notcoincidental.Schein’s classification reflects arange <strong>of</strong> roles from the consultant asa content provider, to the consultantas a process provider. A similarsegmentation is suggested by Nees<strong>and</strong> Greiner (1985), who dividestrategy consultants into five categories.<strong>The</strong> "mental adventurer" analysestruly intransigent problemssuch as long term scenarios forcountry development, by applyingrigorous economic methods <strong>and</strong> leveraginghis or her experience base.<strong>The</strong> "strategic navigator" bases hisor her contribution on a rich quantitativeunderst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the market <strong>and</strong>competitive dynamics, <strong>and</strong> then recommendscourses <strong>of</strong> action withouttoo much regard <strong>of</strong> the client’s ownperspective. <strong>The</strong> "<strong>management</strong> physician"derives their recommendationsfrom a deep underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong>the internal dynamics <strong>of</strong> the clientorganization, <strong>of</strong>ten willingly sacrificingsome objectivity to gain a realisticperspective on what is achievable.<strong>The</strong> "system architect" impacts his orher clients by helping redesignprocesses, routines, <strong>and</strong> systems—always in close cooperation with theclient. Finally, the "friendly co-pilot"counsels senior managers as a facilitatorrather than as an expert, <strong>and</strong>has no ambition to provide newknowledge to the client.<strong>The</strong> mental adventurer broadly correspondsto Schein’s expert model,


7the strategic navigator, <strong>management</strong>physician, <strong>and</strong> system thinker correspondto his doctor–patient model,<strong>and</strong> the friendly co-pilot is similar tothe process consultation model.Nees <strong>and</strong> Greiner further show thatinstitutionally organized strategyconsultants are found primarily in thestrategic navigator <strong>and</strong> <strong>management</strong>physician segments. <strong>The</strong> BostonConsulting Group, Bain & Company<strong>and</strong> Monitor Company are examples<strong>of</strong> the former, <strong>and</strong> McKinsey & Company<strong>of</strong> the latter. Clearly, the role <strong>of</strong>the consultant in both segments requiresa relationship between client<strong>and</strong> consultant which goes beyond acontractually specified arms-lengthrelationship.Turner (1982) uses a hierarchy <strong>of</strong>tasks to demonstrate the extent <strong>of</strong> aconsultant’s involvement with aclient. He argues that up until thelate 1970s, the consultant <strong>of</strong>tenworked as a supplier to the client,but that the relationship increasinglyis built on a partnership <strong>of</strong> mutualrespect aimed at fundamentally improvingthe client’s effectiveness.Turner uses eight task categories todelineate <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>approaches. <strong>The</strong> first five correspondto the traditional arms-lengthsupplier status, the last three arenewer, evolving tasks:1. Providing information to a client4. Making recommendations basedon the diagnosis5. Assisting with implementation <strong>of</strong>recommended actions6. Building a consensus <strong>and</strong> commitmentaround corrective action7. Facilitating client learning8. Permanently improving organizationaleffectiveness.Most <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> firmstoday aspire to work on the highervalue added activities at the lowerend <strong>of</strong> the list. Thus, it is once againclear that a <strong>management</strong> consultants’relationship with their client isbecoming increasingly complicated,<strong>and</strong> that it relies more <strong>and</strong> more onsophisticated contractual arrangements<strong>of</strong> primarily informal nature,such as trust. However, researchhas also shown (Leontiades <strong>and</strong>Ahmet 1989) that <strong>management</strong> consultantsstill have a long way to gobefore they exert major influence onthe core issues <strong>of</strong> their clients. Achief executive is more likely to beinfluenced first by his or her own instincts<strong>and</strong> thinking on a particularsubject, followed by the planningstaff, the board <strong>of</strong> directors, <strong>and</strong> investmentbankers, than by the consultants.Thus, it is unclear how fardown the task hierarchy <strong>management</strong>consultants have really moved.2. Solving a client’s problem3. Making a diagnosis, which maynecessitate redefinition <strong>of</strong> theproblem


8PRACTITIONERS’ VIEWSMarvin Bower (1982), the drivingforce behind McKinsey & Companyover almost half a century, suggestssix reasons why hiring external consultantsmakes sense in many situations:1) they provide competencenot available internally, 2) they havevaried experience outside the client,3) they have time to study the problems,4) they are pr<strong>of</strong>essionals, 5)they are independent, <strong>and</strong> 6) theyhave the ability to create actionbased on their recommendations.However, he does not make clearwhy most <strong>of</strong> these statements shouldbe true.In large companies, the core marketfor <strong>management</strong> consultants, most <strong>of</strong>the skills provided by consultantsshould ostensibly be available internallysince large companies haveencountered most classes <strong>of</strong> problems.Creating the time to study aproblem should simply be a matter <strong>of</strong>priority-setting. That the degree <strong>of</strong>pr<strong>of</strong>essionalism is automaticallyhigher within a <strong>consulting</strong> firm is notobvious. Furthermore, there are argumentsboth for <strong>and</strong> against theproposition that consultants are moreindependent than internal managers<strong>and</strong> experts. Finally, the superiorability to create action, attributed toconsultants by Bower, appears to bea matter <strong>of</strong> training <strong>and</strong> methods <strong>and</strong>not intrinsic to the <strong>consulting</strong> capability.Thus, only the second statement—thatconsultants have variedexperience outside the client—appears to be correct prima facie.Implicit in Bower’s argument, however,is the belief that consultants workprimarily with Schein’s first two models,the expert <strong>and</strong> doctor–patientmodels, since the consultant is expectedto provide an independentperspective on the substantive issuesat h<strong>and</strong>. In Turner’s hierarchy,this corresponds to the lower levels.Bower appears to see the consultantas a partner to the client in solvingunstructured, difficult problems, ratherthan as a supplier <strong>of</strong> packagedmethods <strong>and</strong> approaches.Bruce Henderson, the force behindthe Boston Consulting Group formany years, has a similar perspective(Hagedorn 1982). He arguesthat consultants add significant valueto society (through their clients) byreducing the problem solving cycletime. Exactly why <strong>management</strong> consultantshave more <strong>of</strong> this capabilitythan others is, however, unclear. Butas with Bower, Henderson’s implicitargument is that <strong>management</strong> consultantswork together with theirclients in a complicated relationshipto jointly solve the problems at h<strong>and</strong>.Henderson also argues that the consultantneeds to work in a specializedinstitutional environment whichtakes into account that the key resourceis the body <strong>of</strong> consultants, ahighly mobile resource, <strong>and</strong> that a<strong>consulting</strong> environment is characterizedby instability.Kelley (1979) makes a contrary argumentto Bower <strong>and</strong> Hendersonbased on interviews with more than200 internal consultants at variouscompanies. Among other things, he


9argues that external consultants aremore expensive than internal consultants,they are not available at theright time, <strong>and</strong> they lack an underst<strong>and</strong>ing<strong>of</strong> the client’s environment.This reduces the external consultant’seffectiveness. Kelley also predictsthat the bulk <strong>of</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> workwill be carried out by internal resourcesin the future <strong>and</strong> that externalconsultants will be used only forspecial problems <strong>and</strong> when there is aneed to augment the internal resources.As was quantified earlier inthe article, Kelley has been provenwrong by events, <strong>and</strong> the <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> industry is todaymany times larger than when hewrote his article. In fact, we will seelater that external <strong>management</strong> consultantsare both cost effective,available, <strong>and</strong> adept at underst<strong>and</strong>ingtheir client’s problems <strong>and</strong> circumstances.<strong>The</strong> above summary <strong>of</strong> the literaturepoints at a number <strong>of</strong> propositions:• Management consultants increasinglyaddress critical, long-termissues <strong>of</strong> their clients’ <strong>and</strong> are asignificant part <strong>of</strong> the intellectualagenda <strong>of</strong> executives (correspondingto Turner’s three lowerlevels).• Consultants add value by addressingboth content <strong>and</strong>process issues based on expertise,methodology, <strong>and</strong> generalproblem solving skills (correspondingto Schein’s expert <strong>and</strong>doctor–patient models).• Management consultants worktogether with their clients in acomplicated <strong>and</strong> fluid relationshipcharacterized by a high degree <strong>of</strong>mutual trust.• Management consultants arebest organized in independent,specialized firms with unique characteristics<strong>and</strong> success factors(as argued by Bower <strong>and</strong> Henderson).TRANSACTION COSTTHEORY<strong>The</strong> above perspectives do not shedmuch light on why <strong>management</strong>consultants exist. Transaction costtheory, however, may. <strong>The</strong> theorydeals with the real costs <strong>of</strong> allocatingresources in an imperfect world <strong>of</strong>misunderst<strong>and</strong>ings, misalignedgoals, <strong>and</strong> uncertainty. Since <strong>management</strong>consultants deal with thisvery issue it may be that the theorycan help explain the existence <strong>of</strong> thispr<strong>of</strong>ession.Transaction cost theory was initiallydeveloped in the 1930s by Ronald H.Coase, to help explain why certainactivities, products, or services arecarried out internally in firms—whileothers are bought <strong>and</strong> sold in themarket place. His ideas were neglectedfor many years, but around1970 several scholars started exp<strong>and</strong>ingon Coase’s ideas. Most notable<strong>of</strong> these is Oliver E. Williamson,who over the last 25 years has dedi-


10cated his research to transactioncost theory issues.Unfortunately, this massive effort hasnot yielded a good definition <strong>of</strong> whattransaction costs are, <strong>and</strong> there hasbeen considerable criticism <strong>of</strong> thelack <strong>of</strong> clarity <strong>and</strong> testability <strong>of</strong> thetheory. <strong>The</strong> following is yet anotherimperfect attempt at defining transactioncosts.First, a company’s costs are usefullyclassified in two categories: productioncosts <strong>and</strong> transaction costs.Production costs are those we aremost familiar with. <strong>The</strong>y are all thecosts that are associated directlywith productive activities (Masten1982) such as manufacturing, logistics,<strong>and</strong> product development.Transaction costs, on the otherh<strong>and</strong>, are those costs associatedwith organizing economic activity.<strong>The</strong>y thus vary with organizationalform (Masten 1982). Or as KennethArrow (1983) put it, “<strong>The</strong> distinctionbetween transaction costs <strong>and</strong> productioncosts is that the former canbe varied by a change in the mode <strong>of</strong>resource allocation, while the latteronly depend on the technology <strong>and</strong>tastes, <strong>and</strong> would be the same in alleconomic systems.” It has been estimatedthat at least 45 percent <strong>of</strong>the gross national product in a developedsociety is generated bytransaction costs (Wallis <strong>and</strong> North1986).Ronald H. Coase (1937) defined theterm transaction costs in his pioneeringwork <strong>The</strong> Nature <strong>of</strong> the Firm byasking these fundamental questions:"Why is there any organization?" <strong>and</strong>"Why isn't all production carried outby one big firm?" His answer wasthat there are transaction costswhich determine what is done in themarket, with price as the regulatingmechanism, <strong>and</strong> what is done insidethe firm, with bureaucracy as theregulator. Coase pointed out that"the distinguishing mark <strong>of</strong> the firm isthe supersession <strong>of</strong> the price mechanism."Within this framework, alltransactions carry a cost, either asan external market transaction costor an internal bureaucratic transactioncost. “<strong>The</strong> limit to the size <strong>of</strong> thefirm . . . [is reached] when the costs<strong>of</strong> organizing additional transactionswithin the firm [exceed] the costs <strong>of</strong>carrying out the same transactionsthrough the market.” (Coase 1993).As we will see later, this is exactlythe issue for <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>.Why do companies buy this servicethrough a market transactionrather than doing it themselves?According to Coase (1937) the mostimportant market transaction costsare the cost <strong>of</strong> determining the price<strong>of</strong> a product or service, the cost <strong>of</strong>negotiating <strong>and</strong> creating the contract,<strong>and</strong> the cost <strong>of</strong> information failure.<strong>The</strong> most important internal transactioncosts are associated with theadministrative cost <strong>of</strong> determiningwhat, when, <strong>and</strong> how to produce, thecost <strong>of</strong> resource misallocation (sinceplanning will never be perfect), <strong>and</strong>the cost <strong>of</strong> demotivation (since motivationis lower in large organizations).In any given industry the relativemagnitude <strong>of</strong> market <strong>and</strong> internal


11transaction costs will determine whatis done where.Williamson (e.g. 1975; 1985) extendedthe argument by noting thattwo behavioral assumptions are critical.First, individuals in an organizationare boundedly rational. This, inthe words <strong>of</strong> Herbert Simon (1976)means that “human behavior is intendedlyrational, but only limited so.”This limitation makes it impossible tostructure perfect contracts <strong>and</strong> anycontract will be incomplete even if allinformation is available. Second, individualsbehave opportunistically.This means that they will act in selfinterestwith guile. While some objectto this strong assumption, a number<strong>of</strong> studies have shown that it is validin organizations (Williamson 1993)<strong>and</strong> it is a well established tenet <strong>of</strong>Darwinian zoology (Dawkins 1989).<strong>The</strong> implication is that promises <strong>of</strong>responsible behavior are only crediblewhen they are supported by enforceablecommitments, since individualsotherwise would break anagreement if it is in their self-interest.With the two assumptions <strong>of</strong>bounded rationality <strong>and</strong> opportunism,Williamson (1975) demonstrated thatthree factors play a fundamental rolein determining if market or bureaucratictransactions are optimal. <strong>The</strong>factors are asset specificity, uncertainty,<strong>and</strong> frequency <strong>of</strong> transactions.Under conditions <strong>of</strong> high asset specificitymarket transactions also becomeexpensive. By asset specificityis meant physical assets, human assets,site, or dedicated assets whichhave a specific usage <strong>and</strong> cannoteasily be transferred to another use.Under this condition, opportunisticbehavior can be expected if the assetis part <strong>of</strong> a market transaction.An example is if a supplier invests inspecific tooling equipment dedicatedto one customer (or for that matter ifa <strong>consulting</strong> firm invests in a clientrelationship). Over time, the customerwill be able to put pressure on thevendor since the vendor has no alternativeuse for its investment <strong>and</strong>will be willing to accept a price downto the variable cost <strong>of</strong> production tocover some fixed cost. This leads toa difficult negotiation where eachparty may try to “cheat” <strong>and</strong> wherecomplicated safeguards have to beincorporated in the contract. On theother h<strong>and</strong>, if the customer owns theequipment itself, then the incentiveto cheat disappears <strong>and</strong> the cost <strong>of</strong>creating safeguard contracts is eliminatedsince the asset is owned bythe same company.High uncertainty such as businesscycle volatility or techno<strong>logic</strong>al uncertaintywill lead to more bureaucratictransactions since it will be difficult,<strong>and</strong> prohibitively expensive, to createcontracts which cover all possibleoutcomes. Thus, with higher uncertaintyfirms tend to internalize activities.Finally, if the transactions arefrequent there is once again a tendencyto manage the transactionthrough bureaucracy since the repetitivecontracting cost will be higherthan the bureaucratic cost.


12Empirical research has shown thatthe three factors above indeed dohave an impact on the choice <strong>of</strong>transaction mechanism. For example,Masten (1984) demonstratedthis within the aerospaceindustry, Teece (1981) <strong>and</strong> Klier(1993) in the automotive industry.<strong>The</strong> final important aspect <strong>of</strong>transaction cost theory pertinentto this article restates an argumentfrom the beginning <strong>of</strong> thissection. Transaction costs alonedo not explain whether transactionsare carried out in the marketor internally in the firm. DouglassNorth, the 1994 Nobel Prize winnerin economics, has forcefullypointed out that firms try to minimizetotal cost, not only transactioncosts (e.g. North 1987; 1991;North <strong>and</strong> Wallis 1994). In additionto transaction costs, a firm hasproduction costs. Sometimes, <strong>and</strong>we will see this in the example <strong>of</strong><strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>, transactioncosts are not always minimized becausethe resultant improvement inproduction costs can outweigh theincrease in transaction costs.We can now summarize transactioncosts economics in the followingframework:TRANSACTION COST FRAMEWORKMarket (external)transaction costs•Price determination•Negotiation•Long-term deviationAsset specificityBounded rationalityUncertaintyOpportunismProduction costsBureaucratic (internal)transaction costs•Administration•Resource misallocation•DemotivationFinally, two specific applications <strong>of</strong>transaction cost theory will be usedin the second part <strong>of</strong> the article.FrequencyAoki (1990) has identified some <strong>of</strong>the basic differences between Japanese<strong>and</strong> American style <strong>management</strong>,<strong>and</strong> then used elements <strong>of</strong>transaction cost theory to explainthese differences. One <strong>of</strong> his observationsis that spontaneous <strong>and</strong> voluntarycoordination is much moreprevalent than in Western firms.Thus the need for explicit performancecontracts is reduced. This isachieved by having a long period <strong>of</strong>socializing between employees—thesystem <strong>of</strong> life-time employmentcombined with a promotion systembuilt on seniority. A consequence isthat it is critically important to have


13stable hierarchies with clearly definedroles, <strong>and</strong> it is difficult to injectoutside expertise <strong>of</strong> temporary nature.Thus, while Japanese firms areadept at using suppliers for st<strong>and</strong>ardproducts <strong>and</strong> services, they find itmuch more difficult to use high value-addedservices from the outside.Engl<strong>and</strong>er (1984) applied the theoryto the short-lived practice <strong>of</strong> insidecontracting which was prevalent inthe early days <strong>of</strong> the manufacturingera, especially in New Engl<strong>and</strong>. Underthis system, owners contractedwith suppliers to perform all operationswithin a factory, while providingthe productive assets such as machinery.In essence, the inside contractoragreed on a transfer pricewith the owner, <strong>and</strong> then had thefreedom to hire workers, developwork methods, <strong>and</strong> take whateveraction necessary to generate a pr<strong>of</strong>it.<strong>The</strong> practice broke down for fundamentaltransaction cost theoreticalreasons. <strong>The</strong> high asset specificitybetween owner <strong>and</strong> contractor (bothphysical, human, <strong>and</strong> site specificity)made it impossible to design contractsbetween owners <strong>and</strong> contractorswhich gave a fair share <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>itsto both parties. <strong>The</strong> contractor, havingsuperior knowledge <strong>of</strong> operations,found ways to improve productivitybeyond the expectation <strong>of</strong> theowner. Thus, supernormal rents accruedto the contractor. At the sametime, the internal contractor did nothave many proprietary skills <strong>and</strong> itwas therefore relatively easy for theowner to replace the inside contractorwith his own supervisor <strong>and</strong> workforce.By the end <strong>of</strong> the 19 th centurythe inside contracting system hadgiven way to the vertically integratedindustrial firm where all resources,human <strong>and</strong> physical were under thecontrol <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong>. One maywonder if <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>,which has much in common with theinside contractor, will disappear in asimilar way.In Part Two, to appear in the followingissue <strong>of</strong> this journal, StaffanCanback will deal with these <strong>and</strong>other implications <strong>of</strong> transaction costtheory as it relates to <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong>. He revisits the two questions:1) why do <strong>management</strong> consultantsexist; <strong>and</strong> 2) why do theyorganize in independent firms? Anddraws conclusions about the future<strong>of</strong> the industry.This article is a reprint from the Journal<strong>of</strong> Management Consulting, 1998:Volume 10, Issue 2, pp. 3-11.


14LIST OF REFERENCESAoki, M. 1990. Toward an economic model <strong>of</strong> the Japanese firm. Journal <strong>of</strong>Economic Literature 28: 1–27.Arrow, K. J. 1983. <strong>The</strong> organization <strong>of</strong> economic activity: Issues pertinent to thechoice <strong>of</strong> market versus nonmarket allocation. In Collected Papers <strong>of</strong>Kenneth J. Arrow. Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap.Bower, M. 1982. <strong>The</strong> forces that launched <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> are still atwork. Journal <strong>of</strong> Management Consulting 1 (1): 4–6.Coase, R. H. 1937. <strong>The</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> the firm. Economica n.s., 4: 386–405.Coase, R. H. 1993. <strong>The</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> the firm: Origin, meaning, <strong>and</strong> influence. In <strong>The</strong>nature <strong>of</strong> the firm: Origins, evolution, <strong>and</strong> development, edited by O. E.Williamson <strong>and</strong> S. G. Winter. New York: Oxford University Press.Consultants News. 1982–1997. <strong>The</strong> world's largest <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>firms. Consultants News.Dawkins, R. 1989. <strong>The</strong> selfish gene. 2d ed. New York: Oxford University Press.Engl<strong>and</strong>er, E. J. 1984. An inquiry into the economic theory <strong>of</strong> the firm:Technology, internal organization, <strong>and</strong> public policy. Ph.D. diss., University<strong>of</strong> Washington.Gagnon, R. J. 1984. An integrated strategy for increasing <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>research. Academy <strong>of</strong> Management Proceedings (August): 148–152.Granovetter, M. 1984. Small is bountiful: Labor markets <strong>and</strong> establishment size.American Socio<strong>logic</strong>al Review 49 (3): 323–334.Greiner, L., <strong>and</strong> R. Metzger. 1983. Consulting to <strong>management</strong>. Englewood Cliffs,N.J.: Prentice-Hall.Hagedorn, H. J. 1982. <strong>The</strong> anatomy <strong>of</strong> ideas behind a successful <strong>consulting</strong> firm.Journal <strong>of</strong> Management Consulting 1 (1): 49–59.Kelley, R. E. 1979. Should you have an internal consultant? Harvard BusinessReview 57 (November-December): 110–120.Klier, T. H. 1993. Transaction cost theory <strong>and</strong> just-in-time manufacturing: A newlook at vertical integration in the united states automobile market. Ph.D.diss., Department <strong>of</strong> Economics, Michigan State University.


15Kubr, M., ed. 1996. Management <strong>consulting</strong>: A guide to the pr<strong>of</strong>ession. 3d ed.Geneva: International Labour Office.Leontiades, M., <strong>and</strong> A. Ahmet. 1989. CEO's perceptions <strong>of</strong> strategy consultants.Business Forum (Winter): 51–53.Masten, S. E. 1982. Transaction costs, institutional choice, <strong>and</strong> the organization<strong>of</strong> production. Ph.D. diss., University <strong>of</strong> Pennsylvania.Masten, S. E. 1984. <strong>The</strong> organization <strong>of</strong> production: Evidence from theaerospace industry. Journal <strong>of</strong> Law <strong>and</strong> Economics 27 (October):403–417.Moore, G. L. 1982. <strong>The</strong> politics <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>. Ph.D. diss., CityUniversity <strong>of</strong> New York.Nees, D. B., <strong>and</strong> L. E. Greiner. 1985. Seeing behind the look-alike <strong>management</strong>consultants. Organizational Dynamics 13 (Winter): 68–79.North, D. C. 1987. Institutions, transaction costs <strong>and</strong> economic growth. EconomicInquiry 25 (3): 419–428.North, D. C. 1990. Institutions <strong>and</strong> a transaction-cost theory <strong>of</strong> exchange. InPerspectives on positive political economy, edited by J. E. Alt <strong>and</strong> K. A.Shepsle. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.North, D. C., <strong>and</strong> J. J. Wallis. 1994. Integrating institutional change <strong>and</strong> technicalchange in economic history: A transaction cost approach. Journal <strong>of</strong>Institutional <strong>and</strong> <strong>The</strong>oretical Economics (Zeitschrift für die gesamteStaatswissenschaft) 150 (4): 609–24.Payne, A. T. 1986. New trends in the strategy <strong>consulting</strong> industry. Journal <strong>of</strong>Business Strategy 7 (1): 43–55.Schein, E. H. 1988. Process consultation: Its role in organization development.2d ed. Vol. 1. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley.Simon, H. A. 1976. Administrative behavior. 3rd ed. New York: Free Press.Teece, D. J. 1981. Internal organization <strong>and</strong> economic performance: An empiricalanalysis <strong>of</strong> the pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> principal firms. Journal <strong>of</strong> IndustrialEconomics 30 (2): 173–199.Turner, A. N. 1982. Consulting is more than giving advice. Harvard BusinessReview 60 (September-October): 120–129.


16United Nations Conference on Trade <strong>and</strong> Development. 1993. <strong>The</strong> <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> industry: An overview. In Management <strong>consulting</strong>: A survey <strong>of</strong>the industry <strong>and</strong> its largest firms. New York: United Nations.Wallis, J. J., <strong>and</strong> D. C. North. 1986. Measuring the transaction sector in theAmerican economy, 1870–1970. In Long-term factors in Americaneconomic growth. Studies in income <strong>and</strong> wealth series, edited by S. L.Engerman <strong>and</strong> R. E. Gallman. Chicago: University <strong>of</strong> Chicago Press.Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets <strong>and</strong> hierarchies: Analysis <strong>and</strong> antitrustimplications. New York: Free Press.Williamson, O. E. 1985. <strong>The</strong> economic institutions <strong>of</strong> capitalism. New York: FreePress.Williamson, O. E. 1993. Opportunism <strong>and</strong> its critics. Managerial <strong>and</strong> DecisionEconomics 14: 97–107.


Canback, Staffan. 1999. <strong>The</strong> Logic <strong>of</strong>Management Consulting, Part 2. Journal<strong>of</strong> Management Consulting 10 (3): 3-12A searchable text version <strong>of</strong> the article is found at the back <strong>of</strong> this document


THE LOGIC OFMANAGEMENTCONSULTINGPart TwoStaffan Canback1999© 1999 Journal <strong>of</strong> Management ConsultingReprinted with permission from the Journal <strong>of</strong> Management Consulting


2Editor’s note: In this the second <strong>of</strong>two articles in our series, “<strong>The</strong> Logic<strong>of</strong> Management Consulting,” StaffanCanback, a consultant at MonitorCompany, draws deeply on the industrybackground <strong>and</strong> the explanation<strong>of</strong> transaction costs detailed inthe first article to present a uniquerationale for the industry’s existence.He then develops scenarios for theindustry’s evolution, ending with aperspective on the future <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong>. A future characterizedby continued growth <strong>and</strong> increasinginfluence <strong>of</strong> consultants.Consultants <strong>and</strong> clients alike <strong>of</strong>tenask why the <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>industry has grown so fast over thelast 20 years. Graduating studentssimilarly ask if the growth can besustained <strong>and</strong> if career opportunitiesin the industry will continue to be excellent.Skeptics, such as O’Shea<strong>and</strong> Madigan (1997), argue that<strong>management</strong> consultants <strong>of</strong>ten donot add real value to their clients <strong>and</strong>that the industry is a fad—albeit afad with longevity. Proponents arguethat we live in a free <strong>and</strong> open economy<strong>and</strong> if clients did not derive valuefrom <strong>consulting</strong> services, thenthey would stop using them.Transaction cost theory helps us underst<strong>and</strong>that there are fundamentalreasons why <strong>management</strong> consultantsexist <strong>and</strong> that the industry ismore than a fad. <strong>The</strong> theory alsohelps make predictions about the future.Under what circumstances willthe industry continue to grow? Is itpossible, <strong>and</strong> advisable, for clients torecapture some <strong>of</strong> the activities thatare now performed by consultants?<strong>The</strong>se issues are discussed in thisarticle, ending with the perspectivethat the industry will continue to grow<strong>and</strong> that external <strong>management</strong> consultantswill continue to increasetheir “problem solving market share.”WHY DO MANAGEMENTCONSULTANTS EXIST?Drucker (1979) argues that “the<strong>management</strong> consultant is an extraordinary<strong>and</strong> indeed truly uniquephenomenon.” He argues that thereare two reasons why <strong>management</strong>consultants exist. First, <strong>management</strong>is neither a science nor an art, it is apractice learned through exposure to<strong>and</strong> experience with a wide variety <strong>of</strong>companies in a wide variety <strong>of</strong> industries.A typical executive, however,lacks that exposure: As Druckernotes: “He works with the same organization—orat the most, with veryfew. He lacks exposure <strong>and</strong> cannotgain it. Nor can he simulate it.” Consultants,on the other h<strong>and</strong>, transcendorganizations <strong>and</strong> thus gainexposure. Second, Drucker observesthat executives yearn for objectiveinsights into their <strong>management</strong> problems.Empirical research by Gattiker<strong>and</strong> Larwood (1985) confirms thatclients first <strong>and</strong> foremost look forstimulation, expertise, <strong>and</strong> objectivitywhen they turn to outside consultants.Both these explanations forwhy <strong>management</strong> consultants existare compelling, but they suffer fromnot being anchored in an underlyingtheory. Transaction cost theory pro-


3vides a rigorous <strong>and</strong> consistent explanationfor the existence <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong>. To underst<strong>and</strong>the growth <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>within a transaction cost economicscontext, two fundamentalquestions need to be answered:• Why is there increasing dem<strong>and</strong>for the types <strong>of</strong> services <strong>management</strong>consultants provide?• Why is this dem<strong>and</strong> best filled byexternal consultants who are notdirect employees <strong>of</strong> the firm—butrather contracted outsiders?along the lines suggested in thetransaction cost framework.While national accounts <strong>and</strong> censusTRANSACTION COST FRAMEWORKMarket (external)transaction costs•Price determination•Negotiation•Long-term deviationBounded rationalityBureaucratic (internal)transaction costs•Administration•Resource misallocation•DemotivationDem<strong>and</strong> for <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> servicesAsset specificityUncertaintyOpportunismFrequencyIn Part One (Canback 1998), Greiner<strong>and</strong> Metzger (1983) defined what<strong>management</strong> consultants do: theyhelp solve <strong>management</strong> problems bygiving objective <strong>and</strong> independentadvice. Why is there such extraordinarydem<strong>and</strong> for these types <strong>of</strong> servicestoday, while the dem<strong>and</strong> wasmuch lower 50 years ago?An answer is provided by Wallis <strong>and</strong>North (1986) who studied changes inthe U.S. economy between 1870 <strong>and</strong>1970 by dividing the gross nationalproduct into production cost <strong>and</strong>transaction cost components. <strong>The</strong>yfurther divided transaction costs intomarket transaction costs (i.e., thecosts <strong>of</strong> buying <strong>and</strong> selling in themarket place) <strong>and</strong> bureaucratictransaction costs (i.e., the costs <strong>of</strong>coordinating activities within firms),Production costsdata do not easily conform to thisbreakdown, Wallis <strong>and</strong> North neverthelessmanaged to show that transactioncosts have become an increasinglyimportant part <strong>of</strong> the U.S.economy. <strong>The</strong>ir estimate is thattransaction costs have increasedfrom 8 percent to 45 percent <strong>of</strong> theeconomy between 1870 <strong>and</strong> 1970,with the highest growth in bureaucratic(internal) transaction costs.Using the same methodology, thisauthor found a continued increase intransaction costs over the past 30years.


4To underst<strong>and</strong> this trend, considerhow the following underlying mechanismmight operate. As companiesstrive to reduce productioncosts by exploiting scale <strong>and</strong> scopeeconomies, they need to increasespecialization, which in turn leads toa need for internal coordination. Iftransaction costs did not exist, thenthe largest company would also bethe most pr<strong>of</strong>itable company in eachmarket, since coordination betweenfunctions could be achieved withouteffort. But with transaction costs, thisdoes not happen. Instead, largecompanies need to deploy considerablecoordination resources to realizethe production scale <strong>and</strong> scopeeconomies. On balance, this pays <strong>of</strong>f<strong>and</strong> total productivity increases yearafter year. Reductions in productioncosts are larger than the additionalbureaucratic transaction costs incurred,<strong>and</strong> value added grows.Thus traditional blue collar jobs aredisappearing as production costs arereduced, while the number <strong>of</strong> whitecollar jobs aimed at coordination areincreasing. Moreover, more effort isspent on creating the appropriatecontractual mechanisms inside <strong>and</strong>between firms. Witness, for example,the increased use <strong>of</strong> non-traditionalforms <strong>of</strong> cooperation between firmsthrough different forms <strong>of</strong> alliances<strong>and</strong> partnerships.As a consequence, senior executivestoday deal primarily with abstractissues relating to transactioncosts, while 50 or 100 years ago the<strong>management</strong> task was more concrete<strong>and</strong> aimed at production costreduction. Thus, the role <strong>of</strong> top <strong>management</strong>in a large company haschanged beyond recognition. One <strong>of</strong>the most famous books by a chiefexecutive, Alfred P. Sloan, Jr.’s([1963] 1990) description <strong>of</strong> GeneralMotors under his stewardship, illustratesthe point. <strong>The</strong> book deals almostexclusively with production costissues in sales, manufacturing, development,<strong>and</strong> finance, <strong>and</strong> has aninsignificant amount <strong>of</strong> abstraction.For example, most <strong>of</strong> the excerptsfrom executive committee meetingminutes deal with practical issuessuch as forecasting <strong>and</strong> inventorybuild-up, production schedules,project development issues, <strong>and</strong>cash <strong>management</strong>. Other illustrationscan be found in old corporateannual reports. In Asea’s 1 annual report<strong>of</strong> 1948 the opening statementconcerns factory utilization. <strong>The</strong> reportthen continues to discuss manufacturing<strong>and</strong> product developmentissues, while it totally ignores whatwe today call strategic <strong>and</strong> organizationalissues.Today’s executives must still manageproduction costs, but an evenlarger challenge lies in optimizingtransaction costs. As Herbert Simon(1976) anticipated: "In the postindustrialsociety, the central problemis not how to organize productionefficiently (although this will alwaysremain an important consideration),but how to organize to makedecisions—that is, to process infor-1 Today part <strong>of</strong> Asea Brown Boveri (ABB), theSwedish-Swiss electrical engineering conglomerate.


5mation.” <strong>The</strong> level <strong>of</strong> abstraction hasincreased commensurately. Todaywe talk about vision, strategic intent,learning organizations, <strong>and</strong> virtualcorporations. We find that mostcompanies’ value can not be calculatedby studying the income statement<strong>and</strong> balance sheet alone, sincemuch <strong>of</strong> the market value is embeddedin abstractions such as br<strong>and</strong>image <strong>and</strong> intellectual capital.DEFINITIONSTransaction costs: the costs <strong>of</strong> allocatingresources in an imperfect world <strong>of</strong>misunderst<strong>and</strong>ings, misaligned goals,<strong>and</strong> uncertainty. External transactioncosts center around the cost <strong>of</strong> contracting,internal transaction costs are dominatedby the cost <strong>of</strong> coordination. Transactioncosts are <strong>of</strong>ten described as“economic friction.”Asset specificity: <strong>The</strong> degree that aparticular asset, or set <strong>of</strong> assets, is dedicatedto a given use. In the context <strong>of</strong>this article, the degree that a <strong>consulting</strong>firm's investment in know-how <strong>of</strong> itspr<strong>of</strong>essional staff is applicable only to asingle client, i.e., human asset specificity.Uncertainty: Lack <strong>of</strong> information aboutthe future. In particular, dem<strong>and</strong> volatility<strong>and</strong> techno<strong>logic</strong>al uncertainty are importantto transaction cost theory. Similar torisk.Bounded rationality: <strong>The</strong> notion thathuman beings strive to be rational inmaking choices, but since the brain cannotprocess infinite amounts <strong>of</strong> informationthose choices are not always correct.In this world, it is necessary to begood at symbol manipulation (Reich1991): “Symbolic analysts solve,identify, <strong>and</strong> broker problems by manipulatingsymbols. <strong>The</strong>y simplify realityinto abstract images that can berearranged, juggled, experimentedwith, communicated to other specialists,<strong>and</strong> then, eventually, transformedback into reality.” <strong>The</strong> symbolsare <strong>of</strong>ten qualitative rather thanquantitative. Examples are the fiveforces framework <strong>and</strong> the valuechain developed by Michael E. Porter,<strong>and</strong> the 7-S framework designedby McKinsey & Company. Reich estimatesthat in 1990 close to 20 percent<strong>of</strong> American jobs were held bysymbolic analysts, while no morethan 8 percent <strong>of</strong> workers could beclassified as symbolic analysts atmidcentury. Thus, as the transactioncost part <strong>of</strong> the economy has grown,so has the dem<strong>and</strong> for symbol manipulation.Nature <strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong><strong>The</strong> transaction cost framework canalso be used to more specifically deducethe nature <strong>of</strong> this dem<strong>and</strong>.First, bureaucratic (internal) transactioncosts stem principally from thecost <strong>of</strong> administration, the costs <strong>of</strong>resource misallocation, <strong>and</strong> the negativeimpact <strong>of</strong> demotivation in largeorganizations. Management techniquesaimed at minimizing thesecan, for example, be found within thefields <strong>of</strong> organizational design, strategicplanning, <strong>and</strong> governance. Or-


6ganizational design influences thecost <strong>of</strong> administration <strong>and</strong> the level<strong>of</strong> motivation significantly. An exampleis the superior performance <strong>of</strong>multidivisional organizations overfunctional organizations (Armour <strong>and</strong>Teece 1978). Strategic planning reducesresource misallocation bychanneling scarce resources intoareas where the company has acompetitive advantage. <strong>The</strong> choice<strong>of</strong> governance models help improvemotivation through incentives, <strong>and</strong>reduces organizational slack such asexcessive bureaucracy. <strong>The</strong>se areexactly the kinds <strong>of</strong> problems <strong>management</strong>consultants solve.Second, market transaction costsderive from the cost <strong>of</strong> price determination,the contract negotiationcosts, <strong>and</strong> the risk that there will belong-term deviations from the contractsince all aspects <strong>of</strong> the futurecan not be anticipated. To reducethese costs in dealing with customers,suppliers, <strong>and</strong> partners, executivesprimarily need information. As aconsequence, the dem<strong>and</strong> for market<strong>and</strong> competitive information <strong>and</strong>the intelligent synthesis <strong>of</strong> this informationhas increased dramaticallyover the last 30 years. Services suchas these are <strong>of</strong>fered by <strong>management</strong>consultants.In sum, the increase in dem<strong>and</strong> for<strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> services isexplained by fundamental shifts inthe economy. Today’s complex businessenvironment requires hightransaction costs to function. This inturn leads to an increasing dem<strong>and</strong>for symbolic analysts—the kinds <strong>of</strong>pr<strong>of</strong>essionals found in modern <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> firms. Stryker(1954) identified this trend years agowhen he observed that consultantsused to work on “specialized problems—inplant layout, for example,or in wage-incentive programs,” but“a relatively new kind <strong>of</strong> consultant—the man or firm that in effect <strong>of</strong>fers toset a company’s basic objectives,policies, structure, <strong>and</strong> strategies”was emerging.Reasons for using external<strong>management</strong> consultantsWhy then is the dem<strong>and</strong> for symbolmanipulation to a significant part satisfiedby external <strong>management</strong> consultants?After all, corporate executivescould do the symbol manipulationthemselves, or they could useinternal consultants. Instead they <strong>of</strong>tenuse external resources. As a result,since 1980 <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>has grown by 20 percent peryear. It has not always been thatway, however. Once upon a time,the executives did indeed do thework themselves. Ch<strong>and</strong>ler (1962)describes how executives at the duPont Company struggled between1917 <strong>and</strong> 1921 with how to organizethe company. <strong>The</strong>y created workingparties <strong>and</strong> ad hoc committees, <strong>and</strong>at the same time worked individuallyon position papers <strong>and</strong> proposals.No consultants were involved. Similarly,when General Motors faced amajor crisis in 1920, it turned to one<strong>of</strong> its senior executives, Alfred P.Sloan, Jr., to diagnose <strong>and</strong> solve the


7problem. Sloan’s write-up, the OrganizationStudy (1919), soon catapultedhim into the chairmanship <strong>of</strong>General Motors—without the help <strong>of</strong>consultants.Over time, though, the do-it-yourselfapproach to solving business problemshas decreased in importancebecause it is inefficient. A senior executivemost likely is not familiar withthe particular problem he or she isfacing <strong>and</strong> does not know whichproblem solving technique to apply.This is increasingly true as <strong>management</strong>becomes more complex,while executives remain boundedlyrational (Simon 1976) <strong>and</strong> do nothave the capacity to learn everything.Thus, the choice for the executive<strong>of</strong>ten is whether to turn to internal orexternal experts for advice. Accordingto transaction cost theory, thischoice hinges on the degree <strong>of</strong> assetspecificity, uncertainty due to dem<strong>and</strong>volatility <strong>and</strong> techno<strong>logic</strong>al uncertainty,<strong>and</strong> the frequency <strong>of</strong>transactions involved (as explainedin Part One). If these factors are low,then buying the services in the externalmarket will be the better solution(Rubin 1990): “When a competitivemarket exists, this usually <strong>of</strong>fersthe most powerful method <strong>of</strong> controllingcosts. If a product is made internally,then the firm must spend substantialmanagerial resources monitoringcosts <strong>and</strong> efficiencies…<strong>The</strong>first presumption should always befor purchasing inputs on the market.”What then, can be said about thedegree <strong>of</strong> asset specificity, uncertainty,<strong>and</strong> frequency <strong>of</strong> transactionsin <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> services?<strong>The</strong> two latter factors have worked infavor <strong>of</strong> using outsiders, althoughtheir influence probably is weak. Uncertaintyhas decreased over the last50 years, as evidenced by the declinein volatility <strong>of</strong> the S&P 500 index<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> GDP growth. <strong>The</strong> frequency<strong>of</strong> transactions is usually low,with most problems to be solved beingunique <strong>and</strong> singular.Asset specificity, which can be brokendown into physical asset specificity,human asset specificity, sitespecificity, <strong>and</strong> dedicated assets, isthe most important factor. Giving<strong>consulting</strong> advice does not usuallyrequire an investment in physical assetsthat are specific to the client,<strong>and</strong> when it does (such as the purchase<strong>of</strong> client-specific s<strong>of</strong>tware), thecost is usually billed directly to theclient. Site specificity is low since theconsultant rarely moves permanentlyto the client’s location. Dedicated assetsthat cannot be redeployed areuncommon. <strong>The</strong> only aspect <strong>of</strong> assetspecificity that truly affects the decision<strong>of</strong> using internal or external expertsis human asset specificity. Thatis, to what extent is the knowledge <strong>of</strong>the consultant specific to the client.High human asset specificity exists ifthe consultants need to invest significanttime <strong>and</strong> effort to underst<strong>and</strong>the client’s business, or conversely,if the client needs to invest in underst<strong>and</strong>inghow the consultants work.In Turner’s (1982) eight task catego-


8ries described in Part One, there isan increasing degree <strong>of</strong> human assetspecificity the further down the listthe consultant works. Task 1: Providinginformation to a client usuallydoes not require a client-specific investment,while Task 8: Permanentlyimproving organizational effectivenessdem<strong>and</strong>s that the consultantshave a thorough underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong>the idiosyncrasies <strong>of</strong> the client organization—anunderst<strong>and</strong>ing that<strong>of</strong>ten takes at least a year to build.If human asset specificity is high,then there is significant risk that theclient or the outside consultant willopportunistically try to take advantage<strong>of</strong> the other party, a so-calledholdup situation. For example, theclient may try to reduce price or askfor free additional work since itknows that the <strong>consulting</strong> firm cannoteasily reassign people who have investedin building an underst<strong>and</strong>ing<strong>of</strong> the client organization. Similarly,the consultants know that it will taketime for the client to find, evaluate,<strong>and</strong> build the knowledge <strong>of</strong> a newconsultant. In the end, it may be easierfor the client to avoid the hold-upsituation by using internal resourcesrather than to go through a painfulnegotiation with outsiders.Thus, all other things equal, externalconsultants can be expected to workon issues that have low human assetspecificity, while internal experts dealwith issues close to the heart <strong>of</strong> theorganization. Indeed, this is the waysymbol manipulation was done up tillthe 1970s, with fast-growing internal<strong>consulting</strong> staffs (such as those atGeneral Electric <strong>and</strong> Xerox (Kelley1979)) addressing core issues, <strong>and</strong>external consultants working primarilyon projects with low human assetspecificity.All other things are not equal though.External consultants have been ableto use three other transaction costrelatedfactors to their advantage,while they have tried to minimize thenegative impact <strong>of</strong> high human assetspecificity.First, the theory holds that opportunisticbehavior can be expected within<strong>and</strong> between firms. This opportunismbecomes stronger as specializationto realize scale <strong>and</strong> scope economiesincreases, since specializationleads to goal conflicts between organizationalunits <strong>and</strong> individuals: Amanager in marketing may not necessarilyhave the same goal as amanager in manufacturing, eventhough the goal <strong>of</strong> the company is tomaximize shareholder returns. Thus,the risk <strong>of</strong> efficiency losses due tomisaligned goals has increased withthe growth <strong>of</strong> transaction costs. To<strong>of</strong>fset this, executives more than everneed objective, detached, advice.Who then can best provide the objectivity?External <strong>management</strong> consultantshave the benefit <strong>of</strong> not beingmembers <strong>of</strong> the organization. <strong>The</strong>yusually do not have vested interestsor oblique loyalties. (<strong>The</strong> counterargumentis that the consultant hasone unique sponsor to whom he orshe will yield if necessary. Research(Gattiker <strong>and</strong> Larwood 1985), however,suggests that this does not


9happen <strong>of</strong>ten enough to warrantconcern.)In addition to giving impartial adviceon key issues, consultants can alsoperform managerial audits. Traditionally,this was within the domain <strong>of</strong>accountants, but as the complexity <strong>of</strong>organizations increased the ability <strong>of</strong>accountants to detect shirking decreased(Rubin 1990). External<strong>management</strong> consultants have to alarge extent filled this void since theydeal with managerial issues ratherthan accounting issues. In transactioncost terms, the external <strong>management</strong>consultant is more likelythan an internal counterpart to lessenthe bureaucratic insularity <strong>of</strong> top<strong>management</strong>, <strong>and</strong> to reduce internaltransaction costs due to misallocation<strong>of</strong> resources within <strong>and</strong> betweenfunctions.Second, for those activities that donot carry high human asset specificityvis-à-vis the client, the externalconsultants can build experiencemore effectively than inside consultants.Since they work in organizationsthat essentially are specializedby competence, they will have seensimilar problems before <strong>and</strong> the costfor leveraging this knowledge basewill be low. In contrast, the internalconsultants are experts in how theirown company works, but they seldomhave the size to create an experiencebase by type <strong>of</strong> problem.Also, the external consultant <strong>of</strong>tenhas the opportunity to engage in jointproblem solving with colleagues (Paroush1985). Such joint problemsolving is encouraged by the incentivestructure <strong>of</strong> the <strong>consulting</strong> firm.Replicating this type <strong>of</strong> incentive systemwithin the client organization is<strong>of</strong>ten difficult since most client organizationsare joint stock companieswith very different reward systems.Third, the external <strong>consulting</strong> firmmost likely has higher productivitythan the internal counterpart. <strong>The</strong>main reason is that incentives aremore easily tailored to the needs <strong>and</strong>performance <strong>of</strong> individuals in smallerorganizations, while employees inlarger organizations suffer from bureaucraticallyinduced demotivation(<strong>and</strong> most <strong>consulting</strong> firms aresmaller than the their clients). A parallelis found in R&D where smallercompanies have 3 to10 times higherproductivity than larger companies(Cooper 1964; Zenger 1994).<strong>The</strong> three factors are advantagesheld by the external consultants overthe internal consultants. In addition,<strong>consulting</strong> firms <strong>of</strong>ten manage to <strong>of</strong>fsetthe negative impact <strong>of</strong> high humanasset specificity through contractualmechanisms. In accordancewith the transaction cost framework,it is in the interest <strong>of</strong> the externalconsultant to minimize the cost <strong>of</strong>price determination, negotiation, <strong>and</strong>the impact <strong>of</strong> long-term deviationsfrom the agreed upon contract. Pricedetermination is simplified since<strong>consulting</strong> firms mostly follow thepractice <strong>of</strong> charging a fixed monthlyfee <strong>and</strong> the cost to the client is proportionalto the length <strong>of</strong> the project.Negotiations are possibly burdensome,but are alleviated by the man-


10agement consultant’s propensity touse short <strong>and</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ardized proposals.<strong>The</strong> risk <strong>of</strong> deviations from theintended task is usually small sincemost efforts are relatively brief <strong>and</strong>there is constant feedback betweenclient <strong>and</strong> consultant. Projects seldomtake more than one year, <strong>and</strong>the norm is three to nine months.Consultants further reduce this riskby providing easy exits for the client,such as agreements that the workcan be terminated without advancenotice <strong>and</strong> without a stated reason.What is sometimes viewed as lessthan rigorous contracting policy is infact a sophisticated way for the consultantsto lower the threshold for theclient to retain their services.<strong>The</strong> above <strong>logic</strong> can be summarizedin the following graph:Part One posed the question why wehave seen an explosion in the dem<strong>and</strong>for <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> inthe United States, but not in Japan.<strong>The</strong> answer is complicated. Part <strong>of</strong>the answer lies in Japanese <strong>and</strong>Americans being at different stagesin the <strong>management</strong> skill developmentcycle. More importantly, theJapanese <strong>management</strong> traditionplaces so much reliance on longtermpredictability <strong>of</strong> careers <strong>and</strong> acommensurate need to carry organizationalknowledge within organizations,that it is difficult for outsiders tobe accepted by large corporations.External consultants’ disruptive effectson clients’ <strong>management</strong>processes, so far, have outweighedthe benefits <strong>of</strong> stimulation, expertise,<strong>and</strong> objectivity.MANAGEMENT CONSULTANTS’ DOMAINTask 8: Permanentlyimproving organizationaleffectivenessTurner’s eighttask categories *Task 1: Providinginformation toa client* As described in Part OneNot efficient to useexternalconsultantsImprovedcontractingEfficient to useexternalconsultantsLowHighClient’s internal (bureaucratic)transaction costIncreasinghumanassetspecificity* * * *


11Management <strong>consulting</strong> firms existfor good reasons. <strong>The</strong> nature <strong>of</strong><strong>management</strong> has changed: Unlike inearlier times, abstract issues embodiedin the transaction cost part <strong>of</strong>the economy dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>management</strong>’sattention. Consequently, there is amarket for symbol manipulation—amarket which hardly existed 50 or100 years ago. External <strong>management</strong>consultants are well suited t<strong>of</strong>ill this dem<strong>and</strong>. <strong>The</strong>y bring objectivity,experience, <strong>and</strong> have high productivity.<strong>The</strong> cost to the client <strong>of</strong>working with outside experts is lowerthan the cost <strong>of</strong> using internal resourceswhen both direct <strong>and</strong> indirectcosts are factored in. As we willsee in the next section, this is likelyto hold true in the future as well.HOW WILL THEMANAGEMENT CONSULTINGINDUSTRY EVOLVE?More than forty years ago, <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> was considered“one <strong>of</strong> the hottest—<strong>and</strong> most influential—growthindustries” (Stryker1954). Today, <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>arguably is one <strong>of</strong> the world’smost rapidly growing industries.Many expect that consultants willcontinue to increase market share inproblem solving on behalf <strong>of</strong> corporations<strong>and</strong> other organizations –<strong>and</strong> thus continued industry growth.On the other h<strong>and</strong>, it may be thatclients eventually will reclaim theservices provided by <strong>management</strong>consultants—especially those serviceswith high human asset specificity.This would be akin to the disappearance<strong>of</strong> the inside contractingsystem discussed in Part One <strong>of</strong> thisseries. Under this scenario, the <strong>consulting</strong>industry could stagnate oreven decline.Continued growth scenarioRemember that the key obstacle tousing external resources such as<strong>management</strong> consultants, accordingto transaction cost theory, is the degree<strong>of</strong> human asset specificity involved,<strong>and</strong> that high uncertaintymakes it difficult to use outside contractors.For the growth scenario tomaterialize the following conditionswill have to be true.First, the current trend towards <strong>management</strong>consultants’ deeper involvementin more <strong>and</strong> more aspects<strong>of</strong> solving core problems <strong>of</strong> theirclients will have to moderate; otherwise,asset specificity will increaseso much that external sourcing <strong>of</strong><strong>consulting</strong> services becomes unfeasible.Alternatively, contractual arrangementsbetween client <strong>and</strong> consultantneed to be refined at a pacethat exceeds the increase in assetspecificity (sophisticated contractscan mitigate the negative effect <strong>of</strong>asset specificity; witness for examplethe increasing use <strong>of</strong> success feeswhich tend to align the objectives <strong>of</strong>clients <strong>and</strong> consultants).Second, client organizations willhave to avoid making significant


12strides in reducing internal bureaucracycosts. If, however, clients canreduce the costs <strong>of</strong> administration,resource misallocation, <strong>and</strong> demotivation,then transaction cost theorytells us that it will be relatively moreattractive to do symbol manipulationinternally. Indeed, highly bureaucraticorganizations tend to use moreexternal <strong>management</strong> consultants dothan lean organizations. (A continuedhigh level <strong>of</strong> internal bureaucracycosts will stimulate dem<strong>and</strong> forexternal <strong>management</strong> consultants.)<strong>The</strong> third condition what would haveto prevail is that uncertainty (in terms<strong>of</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> volatility or techno<strong>logic</strong>aluncertainty) will not increase significantly,given that high uncertaintyreduces the benefit <strong>of</strong> buying productsor services from the outside.Were the foregoing growth scenarioto develop more or less as outlined,we could, within 15 to 30 years, seea radically different corporate world.Initially, we would see continued rapidexpansion <strong>of</strong> the <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> industry. Soon therewould be as many external symbolmanipulators as there are executivesin large companies. Over time, thebalance <strong>of</strong> power would shift to the<strong>management</strong> consultants. <strong>The</strong>ywould possess the most knowledgeabout <strong>management</strong> practice in general,<strong>and</strong> their clients’ problems specifically.<strong>The</strong>y would own the knowledgenetworks which will be essentialin the global economy. <strong>The</strong> <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> firms would alsodeplete the stock <strong>of</strong> young, intelligent,<strong>and</strong> well educated people formingthe backbone <strong>of</strong> the future economy.We thus would see a shift inthe balance <strong>of</strong> influence from thetraditional product <strong>and</strong> services sectorsto the symbolic analyst sector,just as in the 1800s we saw a shift <strong>of</strong>influence from the agriculture sectorto the industrial sector.Ultimately, <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>firms would move from being advisers,to taking over the <strong>management</strong>function <strong>of</strong> their clients. We wouldsee a new corporate configuration inwhich the consultants work as thesymbol manipulators <strong>of</strong> corporations,<strong>and</strong> the old corporate structures aredismantled to provide the buildingblocks for those manipulative activities.Consultants would manage highvalue added networks <strong>of</strong> product design<strong>and</strong> delivery activities, wherebythey would provide strategic <strong>and</strong> integrativecapabilities. <strong>The</strong> old corporationswould provide low valueaddedproducts, subassemblies, <strong>and</strong>services to the specification <strong>of</strong> thenetwork operators —the <strong>management</strong>consultants.Decline scenarioUnder the second scenario, <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> would bedoomed, just as inside contractingonce flourished <strong>and</strong> then declined(see Part One). How would this“doomsday” scenario come to be?First, the asset specificity <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong><strong>consulting</strong> advice wouldneed to be so high that clients find it


13difficult to h<strong>and</strong>le the interface betweenthemselves <strong>and</strong> consultants<strong>and</strong>, consequently, decide to internalizesymbol manipulation.Second, large corporations wouldhave to develop their <strong>management</strong>practices to accommodate the needs<strong>of</strong> different types <strong>of</strong> employees, bothsymbolic analysts <strong>and</strong> routine workers.In particular, this would requiredifferentiated approaches to performanceevaluation <strong>and</strong> the setting <strong>of</strong>incentives (a process that has alreadystarted as evidenced by theescalating compensation packageslavished on executives).In a third factor leading to a scenario<strong>of</strong> decline, uncertainty would have toincrease to a significantly higher levelthan it is today.Fourth, the types <strong>of</strong> problems h<strong>and</strong>ledby <strong>management</strong> consultantswould have to become more prevalent.(Remember, as an activity becomesmore frequent there is a tendencyto internalize it.)Should all these things happen, wemay live to see a second version <strong>of</strong>the demise <strong>of</strong> inside contracting.Clients would initially hire away toptalent from <strong>consulting</strong> firms to do thesame jobs as before, <strong>and</strong> with thesame compensation, but now asemployees. <strong>The</strong> alignment <strong>of</strong> highasset specificity with internal sourcingwould over time prove more costeffective than buying <strong>consulting</strong> servicesfrom the outside. Knowledgeaccumulation then would shift towardthe clients, <strong>and</strong> <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>firms would find it increasinglydifficult to provide high value addedadvice. However, since <strong>management</strong>consultants also would be providingan auditing function, <strong>and</strong> assumingthey provided objective advice, theywould not disappear entirely. <strong>The</strong>nature <strong>of</strong> their work, however, mightwell shift from Schein’s expert <strong>and</strong>doctor–patient models to the processconsultation model, one in which theconsultant facilitates <strong>and</strong> the clientprovides the expertise.Under such a decline scenario, external<strong>management</strong> consultantswould work primarily on routine assignments.Yes, they would continueto leverage industry knowledge fromclient to client, much as McKinsey &Company <strong>and</strong> others do today. Butby its very definition, this knowledgeis most unlikely to add unique valueto the individual client. Furthermore,opportunities to work on core issuessuch as strategy <strong>and</strong> governancewould be highly limited. In the end,the <strong>consulting</strong> process would becomesubstantially streamlined <strong>and</strong>highly efficient; on the other h<strong>and</strong>,the industry no longer would be ableto attract the best people. Management<strong>consulting</strong> will cease being“one <strong>of</strong> the hottest—<strong>and</strong> most influential—growthindustries.” 22 Stryker (1954)


14<strong>The</strong> future role <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong>consultantsIn reality, neither <strong>of</strong> these two scenariosseem very likely to fully evolve.Nevertheless, looking to the next tenor fifteen years, several factors pointto the “continued growth scenario” asthe more likely outcome.So far, the <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>industry has been able to largelysurmount the hurdle <strong>of</strong> asset specificity<strong>and</strong>, thereby, redefine an appropriatedivision <strong>of</strong> labor betweenclients <strong>and</strong> consultants. New forms<strong>of</strong> collaboration have made it easierfor clients to outsource problem solving<strong>of</strong> core issues. An example is thetendency <strong>of</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> firms to strivefor long-term relationships withclients as opposed to working on oneproject per client. Another example isthat consultants have been backingaway from the classical model <strong>of</strong>“consultants analyze <strong>and</strong> recommend,clients decide <strong>and</strong> implement.”Collaboration today is muchmore sophisticated than it was amere fifteen years ago, with clients<strong>and</strong> consultants now working togetherthroughout the entire changeprocess. This trend can be expectedto continue.Of at least equal significance—withor without reengineering <strong>and</strong> thelike—there is no indication that internal(bureaucratic) transaction costswithin large corporations will decline.To the contrary, as noted earlier, thetransaction cost part <strong>of</strong> the economyhas grown steadily since the 1870s.Nor is this trend likely to be disruptedanytime in the foreseeable future.For one thing, the increasingly globaleconomy adds to complexity. Withinlarge corporations, the dem<strong>and</strong> forcoordination continues unabated.New technologies such as artificialintelligence appear unlikely within inthe foreseeable future to change thispicture.Finally, there is scant evidence thatlarge corporations will be able to realigntheir <strong>management</strong> processessufficiently in order to be able to internalizesymbol manipulation. Stinchcombe(1965) found that the way acompany manages itself to a largedegree is determined by when it wasfounded. Most large companies arefairly old <strong>and</strong> will continue to be so,even though the information technologyrevolution gradually will changethis picture. In the meantime though,it is unlikely that corporate giants willchange their modus oper<strong>and</strong>i fundamentally.If the above arguments hold true, the<strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> industry willcontinue to prosper. Consultants, togetherwith other external advisers,will play an increasingly importantrole in the global economy <strong>and</strong> mayultimately take on the role <strong>of</strong> networkmanagers. Relationships betweenclients <strong>and</strong> consultants will growstronger <strong>and</strong> symbiotic. Management<strong>consulting</strong> will continue to be a preferredcareer choice for many graduatingstudents at the premier businessschools <strong>and</strong> universities.This article is a reprint from the Journal <strong>of</strong>Management Consulting, 1999: Volume10, Issue 3, pp. 3–12.


15LIST OF REFERENCESArmour, H. O., <strong>and</strong> D. J. Teece. 1978. Organizational structure <strong>and</strong> economicperformance: A test <strong>of</strong> the multidivisional hypothesis. Bell Journal <strong>of</strong>Economics 9 (1): 106–122.Canback, S. 1998. <strong>The</strong> <strong>logic</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>management</strong> <strong>consulting</strong>, part 1. Journal <strong>of</strong>Management Consulting 10 (2): 3–11.Ch<strong>and</strong>ler, A. D., Jr. 1962. Strategy <strong>and</strong> structure: Chapters in the history <strong>of</strong> theAmerican industrial enterprise. Cambridge: MIT Press.Cooper, A. C. 1964. R&D is more efficient in small companies. Harvard BusinessReview 42 (May-June): 75–83.Drucker, P. F. 1979. Why <strong>management</strong> consultants? In <strong>The</strong> evolving science <strong>of</strong><strong>management</strong>, edited by Z. Melvin <strong>and</strong> R. G. Greenwood. New York:AMACOM.Gattiker, U. E., <strong>and</strong> L. Larwood. 1985. Why do clients employ <strong>management</strong>consultants? Consultation 4 (2): 119–129.Greiner, L., <strong>and</strong> R. Metzger. 1983. Consulting to <strong>management</strong>. Englewood Cliffs,N.J.: Prentice-Hall.Kelley, R. E. 1979. Should you have an internal consultant? Harvard BusinessReview 57 (November-December): 110–120.O'Shea, J., <strong>and</strong> C. Madigan. 1997. Dangerous company: <strong>The</strong> <strong>consulting</strong> powerhouses<strong>and</strong> the businesses they save <strong>and</strong> ruin. New York: R<strong>and</strong>omHouse.Paroush, J. 1985. Notes on partnerships in the service sector. Journal <strong>of</strong>Economic Behavior <strong>and</strong> Organization 6 (1): 79–87.Reich, R. B. 1991. <strong>The</strong> work <strong>of</strong> nations: Preparing ourselves for 21st-century capitalism.New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Rubin, P. H. 1990. Managing business transactions. New York: Free Press.Simon, H. A. 1976. Administrative behavior. 3rd ed. New York: Free Press.Sloan, A. J., Jr. 1919. General Motors Corporation: Organization study. Detroit:General Motors.


16Sloan, A. P., Jr. [1963] 1990. My years with General Motors. Edited byJ. McDonald <strong>and</strong> C. Stevens. Reprint, with a new introduction by Peter F.Drucker. New York: Currency. Original edition, New York: Doubleday.Stinchcombe, A. L. 1965. Social structure <strong>and</strong> organizations. In H<strong>and</strong>book <strong>of</strong>organizations, edited by J. G. March. Chicago: R<strong>and</strong> McNally.Stryker, P. 1954. <strong>The</strong> ambitious consultants. Fortune, May, 82–85.Turner, A. N. 1982. Consulting is more than giving advice. Harvard BusinessReview 60 (September-October): 120–129.Wallis, J. J., <strong>and</strong> D. C. North. 1986. Measuring the transaction sector in theAmerican economy, 1870–1970. In Long-term factors in Americaneconomic growth. Studies in income <strong>and</strong> wealth series, edited by S. L.Engerman <strong>and</strong> R. E. Gallman. Chicago: University <strong>of</strong> Chicago Press.Zenger, T. R. 1994. Explaining organizational diseconomies <strong>of</strong> scale in R&D:Agency problems <strong>and</strong> the allocation <strong>of</strong> engineering talent, ideas, <strong>and</strong> effortby firm size. Management Science 40 (6): 708–729.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!