12.07.2015 Views

Teklemariam et al., 2015

Teklemariam et al., 2015

Teklemariam et al., 2015

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Land Use Policy 42 (<strong>2015</strong>) 781–789Contents lists available at ScienceDirectLand Use Policyj o ur na l ho me page: www.elsevier.com/locate/landusepolTransnation<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong>s: Towards an inclusive land governanceframeworkDereje <strong>Teklemariam</strong> a,b,∗ , Hossein Azadi a,c , Jan Nyssen a , Mitiku Haile d , Frank Witlox aa Department of Geography, Ghent University, Belgiumb Department of Management, Mekelle University, P.O. Box 451, Mekelle, Ethiopiac Centre for Environment<strong>al</strong> Sciences, Hasselt University, Agor<strong>al</strong>aan Building D, 3590 Diepenbeek, Belgiumd Department of LaRMEP, Mekelle University, P.O. Box 231, Mekelle, Ethiopiaa r t i c l e i n f oArticle history:Received 15 May 2014Received in revised form23 September 2014Accepted 30 September 2014Keywords:Land acquisitionLand grabGlob<strong>al</strong> governanceStakeholder theoryLand use policyInclusive modela b s t r a c tThe literature on glob<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong>s or land acquisition has extensively described the possible drivers, trajectories,and their impacts. In addition, the concept of a ‘land grab’ per se is heavily contested and viewedas a work in progress. Many have argued on the topic of inclusive land de<strong>al</strong>s without addressing whichgroups of stakeholders are vested with particular powers and interests in the de<strong>al</strong>s. After reviewing thisphenomena in contemporary glob<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong>s and the stakeholder theory of management developed inthe 1980s, this paper proposes a conceptu<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong> framework. Accordingly, the actors in land de<strong>al</strong>sare characterised and disaggregated into seven generic groups, i.e., “inactive”, “discr<strong>et</strong>ionary”, “exigent”,“dominant”, “dangerous”, “dependent”, and “definitive”. The paper concluded that to address the governancech<strong>al</strong>lenges in land de<strong>al</strong>s, a need exists to resolve conceptu<strong>al</strong>isation deficiencies related to inclusiveland de<strong>al</strong> frameworks. Thus, this work suggests that extending the stakeholder theory of managementto the glob<strong>al</strong> governance of transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisition can significantly aid in resolving conceptu<strong>al</strong>isationlimitations for inclusive transnation<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong>s. Hence, a new inclusive land de<strong>al</strong> frameworkwas developed that attempts to integrate the biophysic<strong>al</strong> environment, stakeholders, governance, andinstitutions. Furthermore, this paper recommends that contextu<strong>al</strong>isation of the suggested “land de<strong>al</strong>power-interest clustering (LD-PIC)” and “legitimacy-interest-power (LIP)” frameworks to those <strong>al</strong>readysigned and ongoing land de<strong>al</strong>s using re<strong>al</strong>-world data is a timely matter.© 2014 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.IntroductionLarge-sc<strong>al</strong>e agricultur<strong>al</strong> land acquisitionsFollowing the food and fuel price spikes in 2007–2008, a glob<strong>al</strong>interest in farmlands has arisen. As a result, transnation<strong>al</strong> landacquisitions have gained the attention of governments, internation<strong>al</strong>development institutions, media, and non-government<strong>al</strong>organisations in recent years. Aspirations for capit<strong>al</strong> export,demands by food importing nations to secure reliable supplies offood, an increasing desire for <strong>al</strong>ternative sources of energy, andland speculation are among the factors that contributed to theincrease of agricultur<strong>al</strong> production (GRAIN, 2008; Cotula <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>.,∗ Corresponding author at: Department of Geography, Ghent University, Belgium.Tel.: +32 09 264 46 95; fax: +32 09 264 49 85.E-mail addresses: Dereje<strong>Teklemariam</strong>.Gebremeskel@UGent.be(D. <strong>Teklemariam</strong>), hossein.azadi@ugent.be (H. Azadi).2009; Anseeuw <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2012; Borras <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2012a). Furthermore, DeSchutter (2011) and Azadi <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (2013) restated the reasons behindlarge-sc<strong>al</strong>e land acquisitions as: (a) a rush towards <strong>al</strong>ternative fuelenergy extraction from agro-fuels for which developed countrieshave encouraged transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisitions, (b) increasingpopulation and urbanisation accompanied by the collection ofnatur<strong>al</strong> resource bases in certain countries, (c) access to freshwater(a scarce resource), (d) rising demand for raw materi<strong>al</strong>s fromtropic<strong>al</strong> countries (primarily fibre, wood, <strong>et</strong>c.), (e) the increasingneed among companies in the developed world to earn certifiedemission reduction credits from carbon storage projects, and (f)continued speculation on the future mark<strong>et</strong> prices of farmland,regardless of location.Large-sc<strong>al</strong>e agricultur<strong>al</strong> land acquisitions have repeatedly raised‘land-grab’ concerns and have resulted in the destruction of natur<strong>al</strong>ecosystems and displacement of loc<strong>al</strong> communities (FAO, 2009;Deininger <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2011; Cotula, 2011; Azadi <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013). Althoughthe contemporary views on large-sc<strong>al</strong>e agricultur<strong>al</strong> land acquisitionsare contested, many of the arguments revolve around thedisputed and evolving concept of ‘land grabbing’. Many have arguedhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2014.09.0210264-8377/© 2014 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.


782 D. <strong>Teklemariam</strong> <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. / Land Use Policy 42 (<strong>2015</strong>) 781–789that ‘land grabs’ targ<strong>et</strong> large-sc<strong>al</strong>e acquisition of land in Africa,Centr<strong>al</strong> America, and South and East Asia (Cotula <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2009;Des<strong>al</strong>egn, 2011; Wilkinson <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2012). Others argue that the geographicscope of land grabbing is not only confined to the statedregions but <strong>al</strong>so extends to such areas as the previous Union ofSovi<strong>et</strong> Soci<strong>al</strong>ist Republics (USSR), Eastern Europe, the Middle East,Melanesia, Austr<strong>al</strong>ia, and New Ze<strong>al</strong>and (Visser and Spoor, 2011;Anseeuw <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2012). According to Amanor (2012), the acquisitionof land extends beyond the phenomenon of glob<strong>al</strong> ‘land grabbing’to the consolidation of power over the trans-region<strong>al</strong> v<strong>al</strong>ue chainin particular and a component of the glob<strong>al</strong> ‘mission’ to controlfood and bio-fuel supply chains. Others (e.g., Harvey, 2003) haveconceptu<strong>al</strong>ised transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisitions within the widelyevolving glob<strong>al</strong> capit<strong>al</strong>ist development framework and the distinctrelationships among politic<strong>al</strong> economies working towards theconfrontation of converging glob<strong>al</strong> crises in food, energy, financi<strong>al</strong>capit<strong>al</strong>, and climate change (H<strong>al</strong>l, 2011; White <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2012). Furthermore,land acquisition is considered a component of the combinedoutcome of glob<strong>al</strong>isation, the internation<strong>al</strong> upsurge in foreign directinvestment (FDI), and the liber<strong>al</strong>isation of land mark<strong>et</strong>s (Zoomers,2010).Land acquisitions are recommended to occur via inclusive de<strong>al</strong>sthat will result in a ‘win–win’ outcome (Azadi <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013). Answeringkey operation<strong>al</strong> questions in this process is important, i.e., Whoare the players in the de<strong>al</strong>? What are their interests? How influenti<strong>al</strong>are the de<strong>al</strong>ers involved? Without at least modest answers tosuch questions, merely advocating ‘win–win’ land de<strong>al</strong>s may notresult in an actu<strong>al</strong> ‘win–win’ situation. Land grabbing <strong>al</strong>so highlightedas ‘control grabbing’, which presages a grasping ability tocontrol land and the accompanying basic resources to reap benefitfrom holding such resources (Peluso and Lund, 2011; Borras<strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2012b). This outcome is one of the manifestations of controlgrabbing, implying seizure of large tracts of agricultur<strong>al</strong>ly soundland, land grab, water grab/seizure of water (re)sources (Ganho,2011; Kay and Franco, 2012) and green grabs/seizure of resourcesfor the purpose of the natur<strong>al</strong> environment (Fairhead <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2012).Understanding the groups of stakeholders and to what extent theirinterests and power influence the de<strong>al</strong> will aid in formulatinginclusive and win–win land de<strong>al</strong>s both in de jure and de facto contexts.Lessees who acquire land usu<strong>al</strong>ly enter into land contractsto address their strategic business interests and de<strong>al</strong> strategic<strong>al</strong>ly,whereas actors on the side of the lessor (i.e., loc<strong>al</strong> government,loc<strong>al</strong> communities, and households) may not have such strategicintent and power. Consequently, the need exist to integrate the“power” and “interest” of the de<strong>al</strong>ers in acquisition of agricultur<strong>al</strong>land.This paper first reviews the contested and evolving explanationsoffered for ‘land acquisition’ and m<strong>et</strong>hodologies for glob<strong>al</strong>land acquisition, land de<strong>al</strong>s, or land grabs. Second, this work proposesthe adaptation of strategic management theories, particularlythe stakeholder theory of strategic management, to devise toolsthat are essenti<strong>al</strong> for responsible glob<strong>al</strong> governance of transnation<strong>al</strong>land acquisition. This propos<strong>al</strong> attempts to develop twoinclusive conceptu<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong> frameworks, i.e., “land de<strong>al</strong> powerinterestclustering (LD-PIC)” and “legitimacy-interest-power (LIP)”.In addition, this approach proposes the creation and advancementof tripartite modelling of transnation<strong>al</strong> land based on the powerand legitimacy of the actors and the urgency of the needs thateach actor strives to fulfil. Fin<strong>al</strong>ly, this paper suggests issues forfurther review and data-based investigation. In short, this workattempts to contribute to the ongoing debates on how to ensure thatglob<strong>al</strong> agricultur<strong>al</strong> land acquisition is a more <strong>et</strong>hic<strong>al</strong> and responsibleinvestment and how to establish the power of loc<strong>al</strong> governanceand loc<strong>al</strong> communities within the glob<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong> framework.Throughout this paper, the word “actor” is used interchangeablywith “stakeholder”.Land grabbing: contested and “work-in-progress” definitionsAccording to a large body of literature, there is a propensityfor referring to transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisitions as ‘land-grabbing’without s<strong>et</strong>ting a comprehensive definition for this term. What is‘land grabbing?’ The contested y<strong>et</strong> most commonly applied definitionof land grabbing is large-sc<strong>al</strong>e farm land acquisition foragricultur<strong>al</strong> production by non-loc<strong>al</strong> or foreign investors, wh<strong>et</strong>herthrough lease or purchase arrangements (GRAIN, 2008; Cotula <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>.,2009; Mitta, 2009). According to Borras and Franco (2010), the term‘land grabbing’ was preferably stated as ‘transnation<strong>al</strong> commerci<strong>al</strong>land transactions’ because the concept includes both domestic andtransnation<strong>al</strong> de<strong>al</strong>s, underscoring the commerci<strong>al</strong>isation feature oftransactions irrespective of the size and mark<strong>et</strong>s for productionoutputs. In contrast, Graham <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (2011) described ‘land grabbing’as controlling and/or possessing land for commerci<strong>al</strong> or industri<strong>al</strong>agricultur<strong>al</strong> production that is not proportionate in size comparedwith the mean landholding in a given area, country, or region.According to H<strong>al</strong>l (2011), the phrase ‘land grabbing’ is activist terminologythat conce<strong>al</strong>s larger legitimate or structur<strong>al</strong> differencesand the broad impacts of commerci<strong>al</strong> land transactions among beneficiaries,elites, government officers, partners of different powers,and various intermediaries. FAO-funded studies on land grabs inLatin America and the Caribbean arguably stated the definition ofland grabbing. Accordingly, land acquisitions are considered as landgrabs if three conditions exist in the de<strong>al</strong>s: (a) the size of the de<strong>al</strong> issufficiently large with a commonly accepted threshold of one thousandhectares per de<strong>al</strong>; (b) the need exists for direct participation offoreign governments/companies, and (c) investment on the newlyacquired land is expected to have a negative impact on the foodsecurity status of the host country (Borras <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2012a,b).The majority of the literature labels and characterises transnation<strong>al</strong>land acquisition as ‘land grabbing’. The characterisation of‘land grabbing’ is <strong>al</strong>so notably (food) crisis-centred and farmlandcentredas well as heavily centred on emerging players of glob<strong>al</strong>regimes (i.e., China, India, South Korea, and the Gulf states) andexcessively centred on land acquisitions in Africa. For instance,in the case of Latin America and the Caribbean region, initiativesfor food security, ventures for energy security, emerging strategiesfor mitigating climate change, and promising trajectories forglob<strong>al</strong> capit<strong>al</strong> mobilisation are considered as the four key mechanismsof land acquisition. Land acquisition in Latin America and theCaribbean is characterised by its intra-region<strong>al</strong> nature, i.e., many ofthe companies that acquired land are Latin-based and are <strong>al</strong>liedwith centr<strong>al</strong> state and internation<strong>al</strong> capit<strong>al</strong> sources (Borras <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>.,2012b). Consequently, it is important to proceed broadly fromthe (food)-crisis-centred definition of land grabbing, but it is <strong>al</strong>soimportant not to define it too broadly. This statement leads us toaddress the distinct features of contemporary transnation<strong>al</strong> landacquisition.According to Mehta <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (2012), water is both the targ<strong>et</strong> anddriver of large-sc<strong>al</strong>e land acquisition because its hydraulic complexityposes a ch<strong>al</strong>lenge in describing the entire process of watergrabbing and its associated impacts on the environment and differentsoci<strong>al</strong> groups. This group defined water grabbing as ‘a situationwhere powerful actors are able to take control of, or re<strong>al</strong>locate totheir own benefits, water resources <strong>al</strong>ready used by loc<strong>al</strong> communitiesor feeding aquatic ecosystems on which their livelihoods arebased’ (Mehta <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2012: 197). However, it is quite difficult tod<strong>et</strong>ermine the effects of water re-<strong>al</strong>locations, particularly due tointer-annu<strong>al</strong> variability and surface water-ground water interactions.The absence of meaningful institution<strong>al</strong> linkages b<strong>et</strong>weenwater and land management has eased ‘encroachment’ of the tworesources. The existing ambiguous processes of glob<strong>al</strong> land andwater governance have intensified loc<strong>al</strong>-level complexities anduncertainties whereby the powerful actors in de<strong>al</strong>s can maximise


D. <strong>Teklemariam</strong> <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. / Land Use Policy 42 (<strong>2015</strong>) 781–789 783their interests through such complexities and uncertainties to theextent of expelling poor and margin<strong>al</strong>ised people (Franco <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>.,2013).The size or sc<strong>al</strong>e of land acquired is one of the points of controversyin conceptu<strong>al</strong>ising and reframing ‘land grabbing’. Deininger<strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (2011), Oxfam Internation<strong>al</strong> (2011) and Anseeuw <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (2012)couched this sc<strong>al</strong>e as ‘large-sc<strong>al</strong>e land acquisition’, implying de<strong>al</strong>sgreater than 1000 ha. However, in the work of Borras <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (2012b),land grabbing involves large-sc<strong>al</strong>e land de<strong>al</strong>s in two broadly interlinkedbut distinct dimensions of the size of land transacted and/orthe amount of capit<strong>al</strong> entailed. In addition to the size of land inde<strong>al</strong>s, the amount of capit<strong>al</strong> involved is considered in (re)definingland grabbing, a definition that is labelled as ‘land measurementorientedaccounting’ of farm land acquisition. For example, thefigures stated are 80 million hectares in Anseeuw <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (2012),227 million hectares in Oxfam Internation<strong>al</strong> (2011), and 45 millionhectares in Deininger <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (2011). None of these entities havestated a comprehensive threshold of capit<strong>al</strong> that could be used todefine land grabbing.To summarise, transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisition has passedthrough an evolving definition and conceptu<strong>al</strong>isation in the literature.Many authors preferred that these phenomena were referredto as ‘land grabbing’, a much debatable notion per se, whereasothers considered this expression to be ‘activist’ terminology.Few works in the literature have s<strong>et</strong> preconditions or criteria forlabelling transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisition as ‘land grabbing’. Certainof the criteria considered are the size of the land in the de<strong>al</strong>, the levelof participation of foreign actors, and the size of capit<strong>al</strong> investment,<strong>al</strong>though a threshold for the “size” of capit<strong>al</strong> has not been stated.The concept is further extended to include other resources (i.e.,water) and hence is known as ‘water and land grabbing’. The redefinitionand (re) conceptu<strong>al</strong>isation of these terms are pursued in theconcept of acquiring land on transnation<strong>al</strong> basis.M<strong>et</strong>hod and theoryM<strong>et</strong>hodologies for understanding glob<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong>s‘Land grabbing’ is a hot socio-politic<strong>al</strong> issue throughout theworld and ‘g<strong>et</strong>ting the facts right’ is cruci<strong>al</strong>ly important. To do so,it is highly important to devise effective m<strong>et</strong>hodologies. Althoughsever<strong>al</strong> glob<strong>al</strong> efforts have been carried out to aggregate data onland de<strong>al</strong>s and characterise these transactions, <strong>al</strong>l have struggledwith m<strong>et</strong>hodology (Edelman, 2013; Oya, 2013a,b; Th<strong>al</strong>er, 2013;Rulli & D’Odorico, 2013a,b; Scoones <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013). The literature hasidentified immense uncertainty with respect to what is countedand questioned the m<strong>et</strong>hods used to aggregate ‘land grabs’, andhence, the need exists for development of the second phase of landde<strong>al</strong>/’land grab’ research by abandoning the aim of solely derivingaggregate amounts of land de<strong>al</strong>s (Rulli & D’Odorico, 2013a,b;Scoones <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013).In their discussion on the ‘politics of evidence’, Scoones <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>.(2013) argued for a second phase of land grab research that isfree from imprecise c<strong>al</strong>culations and addresses important questions,i.e., what is actu<strong>al</strong>ly occurring on the ground, who are thelosers and winners, and why. Research that can extend beyondthe fixation on ‘killer facts’ (i.e., those unproven grab numbers)and can provide statements accompanied with traceable datas<strong>et</strong>sis sorely needed (Scoones <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013). In addition to the typeand frequency of data collection, the question of ‘what type ofevidence is appropriate?’ is one of the long-running m<strong>et</strong>hodologic<strong>al</strong>points of debate in the glob<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong> discourse (Scoones<strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013), and researchers must think beyond qu<strong>al</strong>itative versusquantitative debate. Although mixed m<strong>et</strong>hods/approaches are dulyacknowledged, gener<strong>al</strong> r<strong>et</strong>hinking of the form, reliability, mediumfor collection, and portray<strong>al</strong> of evidence is required. Researchersmust share their data in a transparent manner, become accountablefor their findings, reach out to different audiences, and facilitate di<strong>al</strong>ogueand debate among concerned parties (Edelman <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013;Scoones <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013).Extending the stakeholder theory to land useExtensive review of the scientific literature is carried out both inthe areas of transnation<strong>al</strong> farm land acquisition and the StakeholderTheory of Management (Freeman, 1984). The parties involved inboth the substanti<strong>al</strong> and procedur<strong>al</strong> matters of transnation<strong>al</strong> landde<strong>al</strong>s are explored and categorised by extending the stakeholdertheory of management to land use. Conceptu<strong>al</strong> limitations of theusu<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong> framework are identified, and points of improvementare solicited such that the customary binary ‘win–win’ landde<strong>al</strong> framework can be rejuvenated as a multifac<strong>et</strong>ed ‘inclusive’land de<strong>al</strong> framework. Stakeholder theory attempts to addressmor<strong>al</strong>s and v<strong>al</strong>ues in the operation of strategic<strong>al</strong>ly driven investmentventures and was initi<strong>al</strong>ly described in Freeman’s (1984)work of ‘Strategic Management: A Stakeholder Approach’, whichwas followed by a number of publications in academic, research,and governance areas (Don<strong>al</strong>dson <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 1995; Friedman andMiles, 2002; Jonker and Foster, 2002). The stakeholder theory wasextended from an intra-organisation<strong>al</strong> and stockholder (i.e., shareholder)framework to a framework of participatory planning anddecision-making framework in other areas, i.e., corporate soci<strong>al</strong>responsibility (Clarkson, 1995; Hillman, 2001), <strong>et</strong>hics (Agle <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>.,1999), information communication technology (ICT) (Pouloudi,1999), environment<strong>al</strong> management (Jonker and Foster, 2002), academicsand education sector management (McDermott and Chan,1996; Miles, 2012), public policy (Snider <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2003), managementof construction projects (Bourne and W<strong>al</strong>ker, 2005), he<strong>al</strong>th (Lim<strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2005), and public works procurement (Austen <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2006).Continuing the thread to the contemporary ch<strong>al</strong>lenge of glob<strong>al</strong>governance of land grabbing (Borras <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013), we introduc<strong>et</strong>he application of the stakeholder theory in explaining the diversestakeholders in a land de<strong>al</strong>.In line with the power that transnation<strong>al</strong> companies wieldtog<strong>et</strong>her with the powers of other stakeholders, these companies(as in any type of business ventures) apply their own strategic techniquesin pursuing their own business interests and affiliation. Oneof the most important requirements that should be considered duringthe business strategy-making process for companies is theirability to identify intra-institution<strong>al</strong> success factors. By the sam<strong>et</strong>oken, in the age of glob<strong>al</strong> land grabbing, companies are involved inthe transnation<strong>al</strong> acquisition of farmlands, but land has a number ofcomp<strong>et</strong>ing functions. The influence of other stakeholders, (i.e., government,loc<strong>al</strong> communities, internation<strong>al</strong> community, elites andresearchers, politic<strong>al</strong> parties, <strong>et</strong>c.) is quite noticeable. In line withMitchell <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (1997), it is essenti<strong>al</strong> to cultivate a comprehensiveminds<strong>et</strong> if a win–win transnation<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong> is to be established.Inclusive understanding of the key actors and players and successivelytaking into account their interests and power bases aids inmaintaining the efficacy of handling and managing the comp<strong>et</strong>itiveinterests of land use among comp<strong>et</strong>ing stakeholders with differentabilities to influence land de<strong>al</strong>s.Each party in a land de<strong>al</strong> has a unique s<strong>et</strong> of stakeholder(s)with which to work and likely a unique or similar s<strong>et</strong> of reactionsto a particular s<strong>et</strong> of land use propositions. It is a tradition ofland-seeking transnation<strong>al</strong> companies to pay due attention to suchstakeholders’ interests (Mason <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2007). Companies use theirown tactic<strong>al</strong> measures to influence land de<strong>al</strong>s and maintain longtermviability of earnings while strengthening their power throughtheir investment operations. According to McMichael (2013) andAraghi (2003), transnation<strong>al</strong> acquisition of land is considered as


784 D. <strong>Teklemariam</strong> <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. / Land Use Policy 42 (<strong>2015</strong>) 781–789Fig. 1. Land de<strong>al</strong> power-interest clustering (LD-PIC) framework.Adapted from the strategic management literature by James <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (1986), Freeman(1994), Mitchell <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (1997) and Ackermann and Eden (2003).“Security Mercantilism in Internation<strong>al</strong> Relations” through whichcurrent food regime power restructuring is manifested within itsglob<strong>al</strong> economic, politic<strong>al</strong>, and soci<strong>al</strong> coordinates.Results and discussionThe land de<strong>al</strong> power-interest clustering (LD-PIC) frameworkUnderstanding comp<strong>et</strong>ing interpr<strong>et</strong>ations and politic<strong>al</strong> viewswithout a comprehensive land de<strong>al</strong> framework to incorporat<strong>et</strong>he diversified interests of land use and powers of stakeholdersis a major ch<strong>al</strong>lenge (Borras <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013; Margulis <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013).The indispensable role of strategic management tools in mappingpossible power-interest combinations is cruci<strong>al</strong> to the prevailingmulti-polar governance ch<strong>al</strong>lenges of transnation<strong>al</strong> land grabbing.Consequently, we described the relevance of the ‘power-interestgrid’, a conceptu<strong>al</strong> map that disaggregates the stakeholders, theirvested power, and the magnitude of interests they are likelyto reflect (James <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 1986; Freeman, 1994; Agle <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 1999;Ackermann and Eden, 2003) (Fig. 1).This tool is supportive in narrowing down a large number of conceivablestakeholders to a manageable array with which to s<strong>et</strong> thefoundation for a win–win land de<strong>al</strong>. Focusing on the key actors orstakeholders with substantive procedur<strong>al</strong> matters for win–win landde<strong>al</strong>s is an<strong>al</strong>ogous to effective stakeholder management strategicdeliverables. The LD-PIC is useful in classifying land de<strong>al</strong> stakeholdersthat take on centr<strong>al</strong> actor roles by supporting or sabotagingthe intent of win–win land de<strong>al</strong>s. For example, in the strategic managementliterature, Rowley (1997) and Bronn (2003) constructedaggregations of stakeholders into ‘actors’ or ‘parties’ (i.e., those contexts<strong>et</strong>ters, players, and ‘stakeholders’ who are neither contexts<strong>et</strong>ters nor players but other groups who have a stake in the de<strong>al</strong> orprocess). The LD-PIC framework can be described as one of the possibleextensions of the Stakeholder Theory and attempts to explainand forecast multi-agent or organisation<strong>al</strong> functions with respect tostakeholder influences in the contemporary era of glob<strong>al</strong> ‘land grabbing’or transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisition. Although confusion oftenoccurs relative to the theory itself, adaptation of the stated theoryto re<strong>al</strong>-world scenarios is important in developing platforms forissues that contain many interests and stakeholders with diverseinterests and disparities of power (Miles, 2012).An understanding the position and power of different stakeholdersin land de<strong>al</strong>s plays a cruci<strong>al</strong> role in ensuring the accountabilityof companies that acquire land glob<strong>al</strong>ly (Cotula, 2011). Power isthe potenti<strong>al</strong> for obtaining a desired result in relationships inwhich there are comp<strong>et</strong>ing or opposite interests (Winkler, 2009).Although a party in a de<strong>al</strong> may hold power at a certain time, thisdoes not necessarily mean that it holds that power indefinitely overtime and space. This statement does not imply that there might notbe changes in power throughout a given relationship (Elkin, 2007).Power <strong>al</strong>so can be conceptu<strong>al</strong>ised as the ability of a stakeholder toexert influence on its surviv<strong>al</strong> (or interests) based on the ownershipof and/or access to relevant resources (Winkler, 2009). However,interest is the aspiration or a feeling of wanting to be consideredor wanting to take part in a v<strong>al</strong>uable process (in this case, landand its accompanying resources), <strong>al</strong>though selected works in theliterature have labelled this as ‘urgency’ (Agle <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 1999). Furthermore,am<strong>al</strong>gamating the power and interest of stakeholders withtheir degrees of legitimacy is important in an<strong>al</strong>yzing the stakeholdersin a land de<strong>al</strong> in a more comprehensive manner. Legitimacyis a gener<strong>al</strong>ised assumption or a perception that the actions of aparty or stakeholder are appropriate, desirable, or proper withina given soci<strong>al</strong>ly constructed system of beliefs, definitions, norms,and v<strong>al</strong>ues. Legitimacy d<strong>et</strong>ermines wh<strong>et</strong>her a land use claimant orstakeholder is proper, desirable, or suitable to the soci<strong>al</strong> beliefs,norms, and v<strong>al</strong>ues used in the given context. It is <strong>al</strong>so argued thatthe legitimacy of a stakeholder is granted by a given soci<strong>et</strong>y (Agle<strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 1999).Low power/high interest cluster: the ‘objects’Parties or stakeholders with comparably low power but highinterest can be categorised as ‘objects’. These entities are positionedwith high interest, which could be positive or negative dependingon their reason for existence (i.e., mission) and vision. In the convention<strong>al</strong>business world, mapping of <strong>al</strong>l stakeholders is a strategicbusiness prerequisite. Accordingly, this process selects appropriateapproaches to me<strong>et</strong> unilater<strong>al</strong> or bilater<strong>al</strong> interests. To this end, the‘objects’ cluster constitutes the ‘keep them informed’ group, a groupthat has a high interest in the actions of the companies but holdsrelatively low power and requires much communication work fromthe ‘players’ group (James <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 1986; Mitchell <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 1997). Due totheir low power, these groups play a passive role in a land de<strong>al</strong>, andhence we refer to them as the ‘objects’, <strong>al</strong>though they are referred toas ‘subjects’ in much of the strategic management literature (ibid).However, companies are not complacent, and the aggregated effectof many disgruntled stakeholders can grow. In a similar an<strong>al</strong>ogy, toincorporate or consider such parties in transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisitionsand work for an inclusive land de<strong>al</strong> (ILD) arrangement, it iscruci<strong>al</strong> to encourage co<strong>al</strong>itions to increase the power of the membersof this group and engage them in the de<strong>al</strong> (Bern<strong>al</strong>, 2011).A number of land de<strong>al</strong> cases have resulted in highly displeasedstakeholders, and many of these situations are characterised bybi-later<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong>s that neglected a number of pertinent actorswho were actu<strong>al</strong>ly ‘powerless’. For instance, the acquisition of landby Dominion Farms (a Texas-based company) in Western Kenyaresulted in conflicting land rights and land use, and Dominionfarms was subjected to many critic<strong>al</strong> investigations and reviews(FIAN Internation<strong>al</strong>, 2010; G<strong>al</strong>aty, 2012). In 2003, an agreementwas made b<strong>et</strong>ween Dominion and the county councils ‘to develop’17,000 ha of swampland adjacent to Lake Victoria for the durationof 25 years with a possible extension period. During the de<strong>al</strong>, loc<strong>al</strong>community members who used the land for pasture, fishing, andcrop production (especi<strong>al</strong>ly during the dry season) were not consideredand were treated only as ‘subjects’ in the de<strong>al</strong> and receivedcommunication later in the process through loc<strong>al</strong> religious channels.The company followed leg<strong>al</strong> procedures and negotiated withtrustees, <strong>al</strong>though there was severe resistance against the agreementfrom loc<strong>al</strong> community groups (Ochieng, 2011). Despite thefact that many blame the company for ‘grabbing’ the land, whichhas livelihood importance for the loc<strong>al</strong> community, others namedthe government as a responsible ‘player’ in the de<strong>al</strong>. A number


D. <strong>Teklemariam</strong> <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. / Land Use Policy 42 (<strong>2015</strong>) 781–789 785of land use conflicts and fears resulted from this non-inclusiveland de<strong>al</strong>, and the company has invested significant resources tos<strong>et</strong>tle loc<strong>al</strong> grievances, disputes, and court cases. Furthermore, anunusu<strong>al</strong>ly long ranging conflict has occurred b<strong>et</strong>ween loc<strong>al</strong> countrycouncils on the subject of sharing the amount of land b<strong>et</strong>weenthe residents and the company (Anseeuw <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2012). However,loc<strong>al</strong> community groups were supported by different stakeholdersand became relatively powerful in pursuing cases against the relevantinstitutions for s<strong>et</strong>tlement. If the company had passed throughthe appropriate steps of identification and inclusion of <strong>al</strong>l relevantstakeholders tog<strong>et</strong>her with their varied interests and power fromthe beginning of the de<strong>al</strong>, <strong>al</strong>l of those conflicts might not haveoccurred. Despite the fact that the Texas-based company faced<strong>al</strong>l these ch<strong>al</strong>lenges in Kenya, it expanded its operation into theTaraba state of Nigeria and Liberia, where it succeeded in acquiring30,000 ha and 17,000 ha of land, respectively, with state backingand ‘context s<strong>et</strong>ting’ (GRAIN, 2012).High power/high interest cluster: the ‘players’Stakeholders or parties with high power and high interest arecategorised as ‘players’. These parties are the key actors in landde<strong>al</strong>s who receive much attention from the ‘leaders and contexts<strong>et</strong>ters’ group. In many land de<strong>al</strong>s, due focus is given to this group,followed by the ‘leader and context s<strong>et</strong>ters’ cluster. The literaturestates that ‘players’ in a de<strong>al</strong> may deliberately act via sabotage tofulfil their strategic aspirations, <strong>al</strong>though their success or failureis meaningfully affected by the behaviour, position, and strategicinterest of the ‘leaders and context s<strong>et</strong>ters’ (Don<strong>al</strong>dson <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>.,1995). Using their high power and high interest, the genuine roleof ‘players’ in transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisitions is to influence de<strong>al</strong>ersto adhere to the recommended guidelines of corporate soci<strong>al</strong>responsibility and integration of environment<strong>al</strong> and soci<strong>al</strong> governancestandards. Although the state is usu<strong>al</strong>ly invoked as a keyplayer in land acquisition, Wolford <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (2013) argued that statesnever function with the same voice, and hence unbundling of thestate is argued as helpful in viewing government and governanceas people, processes, and relationships.Among those re<strong>al</strong>-world cases, in 2008, the Swiss-based energycompany Addax Bioenergy obtained 14,300 ha of land in the form oflong-term lease agreements for 50 years in centr<strong>al</strong> Sierra Leone. Anagreement was made to produce bioenergy (i.e., <strong>et</strong>hanol) for exportto Europe and generation of electric power for the loc<strong>al</strong> energy mark<strong>et</strong>(for energy users in Sierra Leone). To me<strong>et</strong> its business objective,the company reached an agreement with a number of powerfuland interested ‘players’ in acquiring the African land. The AfricanDevelopment Bank (AfDB), the N<strong>et</strong>herlands Development FinanceCompany (FMO), the UK-based emerging Africa Infrastructure Fund(EAIF), the German Development Finance Institution (DEG), theBelgian Development Bank (BIO), the South African Industri<strong>al</strong>Development Corporation (IDC), and Cordiant managed the ICFDebt Pool to provide the company a debt financing agreement ofD 142 million. Furthermore, Swedfund (the Swedish DevelopmentFund) and the N<strong>et</strong>herlands Development Finance Company (FMO)joined the company as shareholders, elevating the over<strong>al</strong>l size of theinvestment to an estimated D 267 million (Addax Bioenergy, 2012).However, the other Swiss-based investigation group of Brot für Allecarried out a basic an<strong>al</strong>ysis of Addax’s operations and exposed thatthe company would reap a r<strong>et</strong>urn of US$53 million per year, whichis close to 98% of the v<strong>al</strong>ue added by the company’s operations.Those stakeholders who hold high power and high interest in ade<strong>al</strong> do have high bargaining power, which leads them consciouslyor unconsciously into a suppressive and exploitative transaction.For example, relative to the Addax company case, its low-paidemployees (approximately 2000) would receive only 2% of thev<strong>al</strong>ue-added, and the owners of the land leased by Addax wouldreceive approximately 0.2% of the added v<strong>al</strong>ue. Thus, the companyprovides less than US$1 per month for each person affected byits operations or projects, according to a similar recent report byGRAIN (2012). Furthermore, the Government of Sierra Leone actedas the prominent supporter of the community res<strong>et</strong>tlement plandeveloped by Addax for expansion of its sugar cane plantations.High power/low interest cluster: the ‘leaders and context s<strong>et</strong>ters’The composition of stakeholders that can influence the over<strong>al</strong>lcontext of a de<strong>al</strong> could be contextu<strong>al</strong>ised as the ‘leaders andcontext s<strong>et</strong>ters’ cluster. Parties or stakeholders in this group mustbe assured with a ‘keep them satisfied’ tactic<strong>al</strong> endeavour for the‘players’ to fulfil their desired investment interests (Jawahar, 2001;Gardner <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 1986). A number of re<strong>al</strong>-world cases can be classifiedinto this group and are described as follows.The World Bank: The World Bank’s Multilater<strong>al</strong> InvestmentGuarantee Agency supplied a company, i.e., Chayton Capit<strong>al</strong>, withUS$50 million for politic<strong>al</strong> risk insurance in farm holdings inBotswana and Zambia (GRAIN, 2012). The World Bank advocates‘nine billion reasons’ to invest in agriculture. Furthermore, in 2012,the Internation<strong>al</strong> Finance Corporation (IFC), which is the WorldBank’s private sector component, invested US$4.2 billion in largeandsm<strong>al</strong>l-sc<strong>al</strong>e agribusiness and forestry enterprises engaged ingrowing food and fibre, which were expected to employ workersand assist in feeding the world (World Bank Group on Land and FoodSecurity, 2012). However, <strong>al</strong>though the World Bank is blamed for itssupport for ‘land grabbers’ and for de<strong>al</strong>ing with the nation<strong>al</strong> governmentsof developing countries (as ‘context s<strong>et</strong>ters’), it has rejectedthis blame. For instance, the World Bank has rejected Oxfam’s c<strong>al</strong>l tosuspend its involvement in large-sc<strong>al</strong>e transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisitionin developing countries, particularly that of Africa (World Bank,2012): ‘A moratorium focused on the Bank Group targ<strong>et</strong>s preciselythose stakeholders doing the most to improve practices–progressivegovernments, investors, and us. Taking such a step would do nothingto help reduce the instances of abusive practices and would likelyd<strong>et</strong>er responsible investors willing to apply our high standards,’ TheWorld Bank has offici<strong>al</strong>ly replied (p. 4). Payne and Murrin’s UKcompany, which began operating their African Agricultur<strong>al</strong> LandFund in 2007, acquired 30,000 ha of land in Mozambique and otherAfrican countries with support from the Toronto Dominion Bankof Canada and the ISA endowment fund of Vanderbilt University(GRAIN, 2012).The European Union: The European Union supports ‘pro-landde<strong>al</strong>’ policies. For instance, the EU’s ‘Everything but Arms (EBA) tradepolicy’ is an agreement stating that imports to the EU from theleast developed countries are freed from any restriction or duty,except for ammunitions and arms (European Commission, 2000).This component of the EU’s trade policy was formulated with theintention of supporting developing countries; however, this policycould <strong>al</strong>so indirectly encourage ‘land grabbing’. Companies inEurope and other countries will go to developing states such asEthiopia and acquire cheap land, cheap investments, and tradelicenses and will ultimately benefit from the EU’s ‘Everything butArms (EBA)’ import policy. It is a public fact that many companiesfrom the EU member countries, e.g., Dutch and German companies,have acquired large amounts of land in Ethiopia by dismantlingloc<strong>al</strong> communities who have lived on ‘their’ land for hundreds ofyears. In contrast, the governments of developing countries argu<strong>et</strong>hat loc<strong>al</strong> communities are dislocated for the good reason of attractingforeign direct investment (FDI) and not ‘land grabbing’. Thispolicy encourages agricultur<strong>al</strong> land acquisition by European, Arab,Chinese, and Indian profit-oriented companies to rush for largesc<strong>al</strong>eagricultur<strong>al</strong> lands in developing countries in the glob<strong>al</strong> South(Transnation<strong>al</strong> Institute, 2012).The case of the EU’s internation<strong>al</strong> investment policy: In bilater<strong>al</strong>investment treaties, the EU’s investment policy constitutes suchterms as ‘stabilisation’, which are intended to immunise European


786 D. <strong>Teklemariam</strong> <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. / Land Use Policy 42 (<strong>2015</strong>) 781–789companies from any changes made to the laws of the host countries,i.e., developing countries (European Commission, 2006).Accordingly, European companies are encouraged and even havefundament<strong>al</strong> power to influence the state laws of host countries.The case of the EU’s renewable energy directive: The EU hasdeclared that by the year 2020, the share of renewable energyconsumption in the EU will be increased; one example is biofuel(European Commission, 2012). With policies of such types, weargue that the EU and related institutions in other intergovernment<strong>al</strong>and region<strong>al</strong> organisations are among those actors or “contexts<strong>et</strong>ters” who intention<strong>al</strong>ly and/or unintention<strong>al</strong>ly s<strong>et</strong> favourablecontexts for companies and other actors to acquire cheap land indeveloping countries.Low power/low interest cluster: the ‘crowd’The ‘crowd’ cluster constitutes stakeholders with low interestin a de<strong>al</strong> combined with low power to influence the de<strong>al</strong>. The‘crowd’ is a group that constitutes those stakeholders who havelittle impact on the process of land acquisition. For the ‘crowd’,substantive and procedur<strong>al</strong> factors might apply that result in theirpossession of low power and interest in the land. For instance, factorssuch as availability of sm<strong>al</strong>lholder loc<strong>al</strong> development schemes,direct or indirect control of loc<strong>al</strong> administrative institutions, landtenure arrangements, the location pattern of investments and villages,inform<strong>al</strong> land transactions, <strong>et</strong>c. are among the factors thatcould result in certain loc<strong>al</strong> people with low power and interest ata given time (McCarthy, 2010). The cluster constitutes the ‘minim<strong>al</strong>effort’ strategic wing of companies in designing their comp<strong>et</strong>itivebusiness schemes, thus requiring minim<strong>al</strong> investment to win theinterest of these groups (Mitchell <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 1997; Bern<strong>al</strong>, 2011). Theseactors can be treated as potenti<strong>al</strong> rather than actu<strong>al</strong> stakeholdersin a land de<strong>al</strong>, and it may be necessary to raise their interest inthe case of long-run land de<strong>al</strong>s or acquisitions over a longer periodof time. The ‘crowd’ is the group or cluster of stakeholders who,at this stage, do not pose significant land-de<strong>al</strong>-related issues thatrequire further discussions compared with the other groups in theland de<strong>al</strong> power-interest clustering (LD-PIC) framework.Most non-government<strong>al</strong> organisations, community-basedorganisations, certain of the loc<strong>al</strong> administrative structures,members of district or provinci<strong>al</strong> legislatures, and members ofparliament in the recipient communities of land de<strong>al</strong>s are reasonablycategorised in this group. Others, particularly those withhigh power, receive much attention in many of the contemporaryland de<strong>al</strong>s that occur in many developing countries. The strategyused to build capacity, generate interest, raise awareness, andcommunicate the ground-level perceived effects of investmentsplays a vit<strong>al</strong> role in ensuring that this group is reactively responsiv<strong>et</strong>o non-inclusive land de<strong>al</strong>s (UNCHS, 2001). However, the low levelof interest and lower power of this group might change rapidlydue to institution<strong>al</strong>, policy, governance, or demographic changesover time.Legitimacy, interest, and power of the land de<strong>al</strong> frameworkDisaggregation of the concept of ‘stakeholder’ (an overused termin the transnation<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong> literature) into a meaningful classificationis an important step. A good point of departure in this caseis the power, legitimacy, and urgency or s<strong>al</strong>ience model (Mitchell<strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 1997). This model clusters stakeholders according to businesscorporate performance and manageri<strong>al</strong> v<strong>al</strong>ues from whichthe legitimacy, interest, and power (LIP) modelling of parties inland de<strong>al</strong>s can be reframed (Fig. 2). The term is further extendedinto subcategories of potenti<strong>al</strong> actors in a land de<strong>al</strong> described aslatent, discr<strong>et</strong>ionary, dependent, exigent, dominant, dangerous, anddefinitive.Fig. 2. Legitimacy-interest-power (LIP) land de<strong>al</strong> framework.Adapted from Mitchell <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (1997).Inactive stakeholders hold the power to enforce their interestsover others, y<strong>et</strong> they lack urgency and legitimacy, and hence, theirpower to influence de<strong>al</strong>s and acquisitions remains dormant. Discr<strong>et</strong>ionarystakeholders have the legitimacy to present claims in a de<strong>al</strong>,but they are not interested in doing so primarily because they likelylack power or other contextu<strong>al</strong> explanations. The exigent sub-groupconstitutes stakeholders with urgent claims, y<strong>et</strong> they have neitherlegitimacy nor power to enforce them in a de<strong>al</strong>. Dominant stakeholdersare those with legitimate claims and power to influence a de<strong>al</strong>as well as resource entitlement that <strong>al</strong>low them to wield a strongerinfluence in a de<strong>al</strong>. Parties with power and interest but no legitimacyare strategic<strong>al</strong>ly known as ‘dangerous’ stakeholders becaus<strong>et</strong>hey may opt for coercion or violence if they are not appropriatelyengaged in a de<strong>al</strong> or dissatisfied with the consequences of the de<strong>al</strong>.Dependent stakeholders do not have power, <strong>al</strong>though they haveinterest and hold legitimate claims in a de<strong>al</strong>. If the power of thisgroup is improved through different capacity-building schemes,they can easily negotiate with other stakeholders and influence ade<strong>al</strong> or resource acquisition. Fin<strong>al</strong>ly, definitive stakeholders hold thepower and legitimacy to push their interests in a de<strong>al</strong>. The importantquestions are states as follows: Who are those three broadergroups and the seven distinct clusters of stakeholders in a given landde<strong>al</strong> made in a certain country, region, or location? Who lacks legitimacy,interest, or power in the de<strong>al</strong>? What should be done and forwhom such that land de<strong>al</strong>s and acquisitions will end not only in awin–win outcome but <strong>al</strong>so inclusive decisions?Parties or stakeholders that exhibit only one of the threecharacteristics (stakeholders numbered 1–3 in Fig. 2) might bere-categorised as latent stakeholders in such sub-classifications asinactive, discr<strong>et</strong>ionary or exigent/demanding with an<strong>al</strong>ogies to theupper-level classification. Stakeholders who display two of th<strong>et</strong>hree characteristics (those numbered 4, 5, and 6) are categoric<strong>al</strong>lyexpectant stakeholders known as dominant, ‘dangerous’, or dependent,respectively. Those parties or stakeholders who are interestedin the subject(s) in a de<strong>al</strong>, have the power to influence the de<strong>al</strong>,and hold legitimacy in the de<strong>al</strong> and its related matters are definitivestakeholders. A key issue in many of these discourses is the maintenanceof an appropriate triangulated b<strong>al</strong>ance among the tripartiteelements of legitimacy, interest, and power.An inclusive land de<strong>al</strong> (ILD) is envisioned to further address theeconomic, <strong>et</strong>hic<strong>al</strong>, leg<strong>al</strong>, and discr<strong>et</strong>ionary responsibilities or mattersembedded in the different stakeholder groups and sub-groupsexplained thus far. Economic inclusiveness: The ‘profitability of thede<strong>al</strong>s’ or businesses following the land acquisition should seek togenerate acceptable benefit or r<strong>et</strong>urn for the acquired land. Ethic<strong>al</strong>inclusiveness: Responsibility exists in a land de<strong>al</strong> to cooperate


D. <strong>Teklemariam</strong> <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. / Land Use Policy 42 (<strong>2015</strong>) 781–789 787in policies that are fair, just, and right, and refrain from harm, i.e.,the duty to choose wisely among sever<strong>al</strong> <strong>al</strong>ternative uses of landand/or accompanied resources. Leg<strong>al</strong> inclusiveness: This categoryincludes ‘the leg<strong>al</strong> contexts of the de<strong>al</strong>s’, which involves obeyingthe pertinent laws that codify right and wrong. Discr<strong>et</strong>ion<strong>al</strong> inclusiveness:Companies and others who acquire land are expected toact as good (corporate) bodies by deploying their resources for theimprovement of other stakeholders’ well-being and qu<strong>al</strong>ity of life,e.g., devoting resources to improving the livelihood of loc<strong>al</strong> communities.From ‘win–win’ to an inclusive land de<strong>al</strong> frameworkThe governance of transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisition becomes ach<strong>al</strong>lenge in a changing internation<strong>al</strong> agricultur<strong>al</strong> context withcomp<strong>et</strong>ing politic<strong>al</strong> perspectives and strategies, making the existinggovernance landscape more complicated (Borras <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013).Land acquisitions can pose major threats to the livelihood of familyfarming and the rur<strong>al</strong> poor that are ultimately disadvantageous tocountries that supply land and therefore cast criticism on such commerci<strong>al</strong>land de<strong>al</strong>s (Bues, 2011). However, certain factions believ<strong>et</strong>hat such investments should not be gener<strong>al</strong>ly condemned. Manyinvestors who obtain land in certain developing countries faceunknown performance in sustainable land use and forest resources,and most do not work with loc<strong>al</strong> labour and technology, and shiptheir production back to their home countries (Des<strong>al</strong>egn, 2011;Dereje <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013). From this view, such investments might endangerthe amount of available food and increase food insecurityamong the recipient communities. In particular, the large numberof subsistence poor farmers who depend on land to feed their familieswill be affected by land scarcity and rising land prices (Azadi<strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013). Limited empiric<strong>al</strong> studies have shown the effects oflarge-sc<strong>al</strong>e land acquisitions on family farming and sm<strong>al</strong>l-sc<strong>al</strong>efood production (Gobena, 2010; IFAD, 2011).Sm<strong>al</strong>l-sc<strong>al</strong>e farmers or family farmers produce 80% of the foodconsumed in developing countries, but their agricultur<strong>al</strong> operationsare threatened and under continued upheav<strong>al</strong> due to landtenure, land governance, and transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisition (ILC,2014). Family farming must be considered as one of the cornerstonesof sustainable rur<strong>al</strong> development and should be conceivedof as an integr<strong>al</strong> component of the glob<strong>al</strong> food v<strong>al</strong>ue chain. Resolvingthe predicaments of family farming and harmonising this factorwith large-sc<strong>al</strong>e land transactions is essenti<strong>al</strong>.A proper identification and inclusion model for the relevantstakeholders in land de<strong>al</strong>s is lacking, which further contributesto governance complexities and non-inclusive and selective participationof parties in de<strong>al</strong>s that end with long-term transfer offarmlands. Win–win land de<strong>al</strong>s can be mostly sustainable (green)de<strong>al</strong>s and are hence recommended (Azadi <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013); the convention<strong>al</strong>context of win–win de<strong>al</strong>s implies that these agreements aremade b<strong>et</strong>ween two de<strong>al</strong>ers or two stakeholders, but the main issuein the case of land de<strong>al</strong>s goes beyond that explanation. Numerousfurther stakeholders exist with diverse and often conflictinginterests and differentiated powers and aspire to play a role ingiven land de<strong>al</strong>, y<strong>et</strong> they are margin<strong>al</strong>ised. However, it is not soundto develop a ‘one-size-fit <strong>al</strong>l’ inclusive land de<strong>al</strong> (ILD) conceptu<strong>al</strong>model in a contemporary land (use) mark<strong>et</strong> that differs in variousparam<strong>et</strong>ers of location, land use, crop type, and socio-politic<strong>al</strong> andcultur<strong>al</strong> contexts (GRAIN, 2008; Akram-Lodhi, 2012). Furthermore,‘land grabbing’ is a ‘work-in-progress’ concept according to whichthe inclusive land de<strong>al</strong> models may involve re<strong>al</strong>-world cases andtailored frameworks. Inclusive land de<strong>al</strong>s can be sustainable landde<strong>al</strong>s or green de<strong>al</strong>s, which are not easy to construct and hencecould be inevitably complex in practic<strong>al</strong> terms. Win–win land ideas,as described in Azadi <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. (2013), are a necessary but not sufficientcriterion for land de<strong>al</strong>s to be characterised as sustainable or greenFig. 3. Sk<strong>et</strong>ch of the inclusive land de<strong>al</strong> (ILD) framework.de<strong>al</strong>s. As green de<strong>al</strong>s, land de<strong>al</strong>s must simultaneously considerthe systematic and multidirection<strong>al</strong> interactions of the biophysic<strong>al</strong>environment, institutions, and stakeholders (Fig. 3).Our proposed inclusive framework depicts an inclusive land de<strong>al</strong>as a function of three grand indices, i.e., biophysic<strong>al</strong> environment,governance and institutions, and stakeholders, in which each is thefocus of different areas of expertise. In short, the framework can beequated as follows:ILD = f (bpe, gins, sths, Lu) + ewhere: ILD, inclusive land de<strong>al</strong>; bpe, biophysic<strong>al</strong> environment; gins,governance and institutions; sths, stakeholders; Lu, land use, whichis the cumulative effect of biophysic<strong>al</strong> environment, institutions,and stakeholders, and e, effect of latent factors.Consideration of transnation<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong>s relative to the biologic<strong>al</strong>and physic<strong>al</strong> environment that constitutes the flora, fauna,climatic situations, geologic<strong>al</strong> make-up, soil condition, infrastructure,and stability of the area, <strong>et</strong>c. are among the efforts consideredin the inclusive de<strong>al</strong>s. The ILD should not only protect and preserv<strong>et</strong>he biophysic<strong>al</strong> environment but <strong>al</strong>so should be viewed fromthe context of power and interest in moving transnation<strong>al</strong> capit<strong>al</strong>for b<strong>et</strong>ter benefit maximisation through the use of the biophysic<strong>al</strong>resources of the host countries and communities. Transnation<strong>al</strong>acquisition of land must be viewed from the broader context ofoccupying land and its accompanying resources, i.e., water forsm<strong>al</strong>l-sc<strong>al</strong>e land-holding peasants and loc<strong>al</strong> households (Ganho,2011; Kay and Franco, 2012). Excessive focus on the land per seruns the risk of overlooking the basic drivers behind transnation<strong>al</strong>land acquisition, i.e., greed for power in the glob<strong>al</strong> food and inputsupply chain and harnessing control over biophysic<strong>al</strong> prerequisitesto further capit<strong>al</strong> accumulation.Governance and institutions are the most important variable inthe ILD framework, which is clear but illusive in many of the contemporaryland de<strong>al</strong>s. Accountable, consensus-oriented, effectiveand efficient, equitable and inclusive, participatory, and responsiveand transparent governance of land use and its associatedresources are prerequisites for an inclusive process in transnation<strong>al</strong>land de<strong>al</strong>s. Assessing the adherence of transnation<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong>sto the principles of accountability, transparency, and responsibleagricultur<strong>al</strong> investment contributes to ensuring sustainable landuse rather than simple focus on the exchange of land ownershipor land use. Assessment of the contexts and improvement factorsrelated to land (i.e., policies, legislations, laws, directives, and mark<strong>et</strong>)in such an approach could aid in facilitating good governance


788 D. <strong>Teklemariam</strong> <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. / Land Use Policy 42 (<strong>2015</strong>) 781–789and transactions of land. As discussed in the previous sections, thestakeholders must be considered, and their genuine participation isa requirement for inclusive de<strong>al</strong>s. Protection of vulnerable groups,i.e., loc<strong>al</strong> economies, soci<strong>al</strong> fabric, and cultures, is <strong>al</strong>so a basic need.The right to food and nutrition<strong>al</strong> sovereignty as well as respect forthe available soci<strong>al</strong> norms and practices are among the componentsof responsible agricultur<strong>al</strong> investments. Fin<strong>al</strong>ly, synchronising theinterplay among the biophysic<strong>al</strong> environment, stakeholders, governance,and institutions in the context of comp<strong>et</strong>itive land use isessenti<strong>al</strong>.Adapting and refining the proposed frameworks: checklistquestionsThe need exists to bridge the gap b<strong>et</strong>ween “gener<strong>al</strong>ised”and “contextu<strong>al</strong>ised” knowledge (and information) concerningtransnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisition. Most of the gener<strong>al</strong>ised conceptu<strong>al</strong>isationsand sources neglect the importance of powerless andpowerful (y<strong>et</strong> uninterested) stakeholders in de<strong>al</strong>s surrounding landuse (Amanor, 2012; Anseeuw <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2012). The important questionsare: Who are the three broader groups and seven distinctsub-groups of stakeholders in a land de<strong>al</strong>? Who lacks legitimacy,interest, or power in the de<strong>al</strong>? What should be carried out by whomand for whom such that land de<strong>al</strong>s and acquisitions will end upwith not only win–win outcomes but <strong>al</strong>so inclusive decisions? Forland de<strong>al</strong>s to become inclusive resource use agreements and to begoverned in line with meaningful environment<strong>al</strong> and soci<strong>al</strong> governancestandards, these following fundament<strong>al</strong> questions shouldbe addressed in re<strong>al</strong>-world contexts, land use types, and socioeconomicand politic<strong>al</strong> s<strong>et</strong>tings.ConclusionRecent works on transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisition argue towardswin–win land de<strong>al</strong>s or ‘green de<strong>al</strong>s’ (Azadi <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>., 2013). However,a ‘win–win’ situation is a necessary but not sufficient condition forland de<strong>al</strong>s to become inclusive or effective green de<strong>al</strong>s. To obtainan inclusive land de<strong>al</strong>, the need exists to broaden the groups ofstakeholders (i.e., in addition to the investor and investee) accordingto various but relevant param<strong>et</strong>ers. By extending the evolvingstakeholder theory of management to the emerging governancech<strong>al</strong>lenges of transnation<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong>s, we propose a new conceptknown as the land de<strong>al</strong> power-interest clustering (LD-PIC)framework. Stakeholders in a transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisition are categorisedinto either four or seven generic groups depending on thepower, interest, and legitimacy with which they are vested. First,according to the LD-PIC, actors in land de<strong>al</strong>s can be categorisedinto four groups, i.e., subjects, players, leaders-context s<strong>et</strong>ters, andcrowd. The first group of ‘subjects’ are those groups of stakeholderswith high interest in the land considered in a de<strong>al</strong> but with lowpower to influence both the process and outcome of the de<strong>al</strong>. Incontrast, the second group of ‘players’ are those stakeholders whohave high power and high interest, including the designers and re<strong>al</strong>actors of de<strong>al</strong>s that use the contexts s<strong>et</strong> by the third group of leadersand context s<strong>et</strong>ters. The leaders and context s<strong>et</strong>ters group consistsof stakeholders with low interest in the de<strong>al</strong>s but comparativelyhigh power in influencing the context of the de<strong>al</strong>. The last y<strong>et</strong> notleast group of the ‘crowd’ are stakeholders with low power and lowinterest relative to land de<strong>al</strong>s.By adapting the concept of ‘legitimacy’ into our LD-PIC framework,we introduce the legitimacy, interest, and power (LIP) landde<strong>al</strong> framework. Accordingly, seven distinct groups of stakeholdersare created from the context of transnation<strong>al</strong> land acquisition,i.e., inactive, discr<strong>et</strong>ionary, exigent, dominant, dangerous, dependent,and definitive. Although <strong>al</strong>l of these groups of stakeholders do exist,unfortunately, the land use agreements that have been made thusfar have occurred b<strong>et</strong>ween only two parties, i.e., the leaser andlessee. However, if an inclusive land de<strong>al</strong> is assumed, the interplayb<strong>et</strong>ween the leaser and lessee and <strong>al</strong>so among these sevengroups of stakeholders as well as its implications for sustainableland use must be properly understood. Considering the systematicand multidirection<strong>al</strong> interactions of the biophysic<strong>al</strong> environment,institutions, and stakeholders, we offer an inclusive land de<strong>al</strong> (ILD)framework. The framework portrays the inclusive land de<strong>al</strong> as afunction of three grand variables: biophysic<strong>al</strong> environment, governanceand institutions, and stakeholders. Fin<strong>al</strong>ly, understandingand improving the theor<strong>et</strong>ic<strong>al</strong> re<strong>al</strong>m of the ILD framework of stakeholdersis a current issue, and it is cruci<strong>al</strong> to apply or use thisframework in the further steps of assessing specific land de<strong>al</strong>s, landuse, crops, governance, institution<strong>al</strong>, and location cases.AcknowledgementThe lead author is a beneficiary of a doctor<strong>al</strong> research grant fromGhent University’s Speci<strong>al</strong> Research Fund (BOF). We thank GhentUniversity. Thanks <strong>al</strong>so to Mekelle University, the Internation<strong>al</strong>Foundation for Science (IFS), Ministry of Agriculture of Ethiopia,and Ethiopian Investment Authority. Furthermore, the constructivecomments which were provided by two anonymous reviewersare strongly acknowledged.ReferencesAckermann, F., Eden, C., 2003. Powerful and interested stakeholders matter: theiridentification and management. In: American Academy of Management Conference,Seatle, USA, 2003-08-01.Addax Bioenergy, 2012. Prospect of Bio-fuels in Sierra Leone. Self-Publishingat GRIN, Available from: http://www.grin.com/en/e-book/230290/prospect-of-bio-fuels-in-sierra-leone (accessed 14.02.13).Agle, B.R., Mitchell, R.K., Sonnenfeld, J.A., 1999. Who matters to CEOs? An investigationof stakeholder attributes and s<strong>al</strong>ience, corporate performance, and CEOv<strong>al</strong>ues. Acad. Manag. J. 42 (5), 507–525.Akram-Lodhi, A.H., 2012. Contextu<strong>al</strong>ising land grabbing: contemporary land de<strong>al</strong>s,the glob<strong>al</strong> subsistence crisis and the world food system. Can. J. Dev. Stud./Rev.33 (2.).Amanor, K.S., 2012. Glob<strong>al</strong> resource grabs, agribusiness concentration and the sm<strong>al</strong>lholder:two West African case studies. J. Peasant Stud. 39 (3–4), 731–749.Anseeuw, W., Boche, M., Breu, T., Giger, M., Lay, J., Messerli, P., Nolte,K., 2012. Transnation<strong>al</strong> Land De<strong>al</strong>s for Agriculture in the Glob<strong>al</strong> SouthAn<strong>al</strong>ytic<strong>al</strong> Report based on the Land Matrix Database. CDE/CIRAD/GIGA,Bern/Montpellier/Hamburg, Available at: http://www.landco<strong>al</strong>ition.org/sites/default/files/publication/1254/ (accessed 10.02.13).Araghi, F., 2003. Food regimes and the production of v<strong>al</strong>ue: some m<strong>et</strong>hodologic<strong>al</strong>issues. J. Peasant Stud. 30 (2), 41–70.Austen, S., Seymour, R., Brown, K., Furneaux, C., McCabe, A., 2006. Multi-OutcomeConstruction Policies: Literature Review on Stakeholder Theory, Brisbane Qld4000, Austr<strong>al</strong>ia.Azadi, H., Houshyar, E., Zarafshani, K., Hosseininia, G., Witlox, F., 2013. Agricultur<strong>al</strong>outsourcing: a two-headed coin? Glob<strong>al</strong> Plan<strong>et</strong>. Change 100, 20–27.Bern<strong>al</strong>, A.M., 2011. Power, powerlessness and p<strong>et</strong>roleum: indigenous environment<strong>al</strong>claims and the limits of transnation<strong>al</strong> law. N. Polit. Sci. 33 (2), 143–167.Borras S.M. Jr., Franco, J.C., 2010. Towards a broader view of the politics of glob<strong>al</strong>land grab: r<strong>et</strong>hinking land issues, reframing resistance. In: ICAS Working PaperSeries No. 001. Initiatives in Critic<strong>al</strong> Agrarian Studies (ICAS)/Land De<strong>al</strong> PoliticsInitiative (LDPI)/Transnation<strong>al</strong> Institute (TSI).Borras, S.M., Kay, C., Gómez, S., Wilkinson, J., 2012a. Land grabbing and glob<strong>al</strong> capit<strong>al</strong>istaccumulation: key features in Latin America. Can. J. Dev. Stud./Rev. 33 (4),402–416.Borras, S.M., Franco, J.C., Gómez, S., Kay, C., Spoor, M., 2012b. Land grabbing in LatinAmerica and the Caribbean. J. Peasant Stud. 39 (3–4), 845–872.Borras, S.M., Franco, J.C., Wang, C., 2013. The ch<strong>al</strong>lenge of glob<strong>al</strong> governance of landgrabbing: changing internation<strong>al</strong> agricultur<strong>al</strong> context and comp<strong>et</strong>ing politic<strong>al</strong>views and strategies. Glob<strong>al</strong>izations 10 (1), 161–179.Bourne, L., W<strong>al</strong>ker, D.H.T., 2005. Visu<strong>al</strong>ising and mapping stakeholder influence.Manag. Decis. 43 (5), 649–660.Bronn, S.P., 2003. A reflective stakeholder approach: co-orientation as a basis forcommunication learning. J. Commun. Manag. 7 (4), 291–303.Bues, B.A., 2011. Agricultur<strong>al</strong> foreign direct investment and water rights: an institution<strong>al</strong>an<strong>al</strong>ysis from glob<strong>al</strong> land grabbing. In: Glob<strong>al</strong> Land Grabbing. Land De<strong>al</strong>sPolitics Initiative (LDPI), Sussex.Clarkson, M.E., 1995. A stakeholder framework for an<strong>al</strong>ysing and ev<strong>al</strong>uating corporatesoci<strong>al</strong> performance. Acad. Manag. Rev. 20 (1), 92–117.Cotula, L., 2011. Land De<strong>al</strong>s in Africa: What is in the Contracts? Internation<strong>al</strong> Institutefor Environment and Development (IIED), London, UK.


D. <strong>Teklemariam</strong> <strong>et</strong> <strong>al</strong>. / Land Use Policy 42 (<strong>2015</strong>) 781–789 789Cotula, L., Vermeulen, S., Leonard, R., Keeley, J., 2009. Land Grab or DevelopmentOpportunity? Internation<strong>al</strong> Land De<strong>al</strong>s in Africa Land Grab or DevelopmentOpportunity? FAO, IIED and IFAD, London/Rome.Dereje, T., Witlox, F., Azadi, H., Mitiku, H., Nyssen, J.,2013. Internation<strong>al</strong> land de<strong>al</strong>s,loc<strong>al</strong> people’s livelihood, and environment nexus (How to create win–winland de<strong>al</strong>s in Ethiopia?)). In: Geophysic<strong>al</strong> Research Abstracts. Gener<strong>al</strong> Assemblyof the European Geosciences Union, Veinna, Austria, p. 1, Available from:http://me<strong>et</strong>ingorganizer.copernicus.org/ (accessed 23.10.13).De Schutter, O., 2011. How not to think of land-grabbing: three critiques of largesc<strong>al</strong>einvestments in farmland. J. Peasant Stud. 38 (2), 249–279.Des<strong>al</strong>egn, R., 2011. Land to Investors: Large-Sc<strong>al</strong>e Land Transfers in Ethiopia. AddisAbaba, Available from: http://www.landgovernance.org/ (accessed 15.10.12).Don<strong>al</strong>dson, T., Preston, L.E., Preston, L.E.E.E., 1995. The stakeholder theory of thecorporation: concepts, evidence, and implications. Acad. Manag. Rev. 20 (1),65–91.Edelman, M., Oya, C., Borras S.M. Jr., 2013. Glob<strong>al</strong> land grabs: historic<strong>al</strong> processes,theor<strong>et</strong>ic<strong>al</strong> and m<strong>et</strong>hodologic<strong>al</strong> implications and current trajectories. ThirdWorld Q. 34 (9), 517–1531.Elkin, J., 2007. A review of the stakeholder theory. In: Geare, A. (Ed.), Otago ManagementGraduate Review 5, 17–26. Department of Management, University ofOtago.European Commission, 2000. EU Trade Concessions to Least Developed Countries:Everything but Arms Propos<strong>al</strong>. Possible Impacts on the Agricultur<strong>al</strong> Sector, Brussels,Available from: http://www2.weed-online.org/eu/texte/first eba ias.pdf(accessed 11.01.13).European Commission, 2012. Renewable Energy: A Major Player in the EuropeanEnergy Mark<strong>et</strong>, Available from: http://ec.europa.eu/energy/renewables/doc/communication/2012/comm en.pdf (accessed 03.01.13).European Commission, 2006, May. Upgrading the EU Investment Policy., pp. 1–4,Available from: http://www.iisd.org/pdf/2006/tas upgrading eu.pdf (accessed10.01 13).Fairhead, J., Leach, M., Scoones, I., 2012. Green grabbing: a new appropriation ofnature? J. Peasant Stud. 39 (2), 237–261.FAO, 2009. How to Feed the World in 2050, Available from: http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/templates/wsfs/docs/expert paper/How to Feed the World in 2050.pdf (accessed 20.01.13).FIAN Internation<strong>al</strong>, 2010. Land grabbing in Kenya and Mozambique: A report on tworesearch missions – And a Human Rights An<strong>al</strong>ysis of Land Grabbing. Heidelberg,Germany.Franco, J., Mehta, L., Veldwisch, G.J., 2013. The glob<strong>al</strong> politics of water grabbing. ThirdWorld Quarterly 34 (9), 1651–1675.Freeman, R.E., 1984. Strategic Management, 1st ed. Copp Clark Pitman, Toronto,Associated Companies.Freeman, R.E., 1994. The politics of stakeholder theory: some future directions. Bus.Ethics Q. 4 (4), 409.Friedman, A.L., Miles, S., 2002. Developing stakeholder theory. J. Manag. Stud. 39 (1),1–21.G<strong>al</strong>aty, B.J.G., 2012. “Unused” land and unfulfilled promises: justifications fordisplacing communities in East Africa glob<strong>al</strong> land grabbing II. Paper presentedat the Internation<strong>al</strong> Academic Conference on Glob<strong>al</strong> Land Grabbing II,pp. 1–14.Ganho, A.S., 2011. Is water the hidden Agenda of agricultur<strong>al</strong> land acquisition insub-Saharan Africa? Glob<strong>al</strong> land grabbing. In: Glob<strong>al</strong> Land Grabbing. Land De<strong>al</strong>Politics Initiative (LDPI) in collaboration with the Journ<strong>al</strong> of Peasant Studies andhosted by the Future Agricultures Consortium at the Institute of DevelopmentStudies, University of Sussex.GardnerF J.R., Rachlin, R., Sweeny, A., 1986. Handbook of Strategic Planning, 99th ed.John Wiley & Sons, New York.Gobena, M., 2010. Effects of Large-sc<strong>al</strong>e Land acquisition in Rur<strong>al</strong> Ethiopia: The Caseof Bako-Tibe Woreda Thesis No xx. Swedish University of Agricultur<strong>al</strong> Sciences,Sweden Examiner.Graham, A., Aubry, S., Künnemann, R., 2011. The role of the EU in land grabbingin Africa – CSO monitoring 2009–2010 “Advancing African Agriculture” (AAA):the impact of Europe’s policies and practices on African agriculture and foodsecurity glob<strong>al</strong> land grabbing. Paper presented at the Internation<strong>al</strong> Conferenceon Glob<strong>al</strong> Land Grabbing I.GRAIN, 2008. The 2008 Land Grab for Food and Financi<strong>al</strong> Security, Availablefrom: http://www.grain.org/system/old/briefings files/landgrab-2008-en.pdf(accessed 20.01.13).GRAIN, 2012. Who’s Behind the Land Grabs? A Look at Some of the People Pursuingor Supporting Large Farmland Grabs Around the World. Barcelona, Spain.H<strong>al</strong>l, R., 2011. Land grabbing in Southern Africa: the many faces of the investor rush.Rev. Afr. Polit. Econ. 38 (128), 193–214.Harvey, D., 2003. The New Imperi<strong>al</strong>ism. Oxford University Press, Oxford.Hillman, A.M.Y.J., 2001. Stakeholder v<strong>al</strong>ue, stakeholder management, and soci<strong>al</strong>issues: what is the bottom line? Strateg. Manag. J. 22 (2), 125–139.IFAD, 2011. Enabling Poor Rur<strong>al</strong> People to Overcome Poverty, Rur<strong>al</strong> Poverty Report2011. Rome, It<strong>al</strong>y.ILC, 2014. Internation Year of Family Farming IYFF-2014: Feeding the World,Caring for the Earth. 2014 The Internation<strong>al</strong> Year of Family Farming(January), Available from: http://www.familyfarmingcampaign.n<strong>et</strong>/archivos/comunicacion/ poster cientificoen.pdf (accessed 17.01.13).James, G., Robert, R., Allen, S., 1986. Handbook of Strategic Planning, 99th ed. JohnWiley & Sons, New York.Jawahar, I.M.M.L.G., 2001. Twards a descriptive stakeholder theory. Acad. Manag.Rev. 26 (3), 397–414.Jonker, J., Foster, D., 2002. Stakeholder excellence? Framing the evolution and complexityof a stakeholder perspective of the firm. Corp. Soc. Responsib. Environ.Manag. 9 (4), 187–195.Kay, S., Franco, J., 2012. The Glob<strong>al</strong> Water Grab, A Primer. Amsterdam,The N<strong>et</strong>herlands, Available from: http://www.tni.org/sites/www.tni.org/files/download/watergrabbingprimer-<strong>al</strong>tcover2.pdf (accessed 14.12.12).Deininger, K., Derek, B., Lindsay, J., Norton, A., Selod, H., Stickler, M., 2011. RisingGlob<strong>al</strong> Interest in Farmland, Can It Yield Sustainable and Equitable Benefits?The World Bank, Washington, DC.Lim, G., Ahn, H., Lee, H., 2005. Formulating strategies for stakeholder management:a case-based reasoning approach. Expert Syst. Appl. 28 (4), 831–840.Margulis, M.E., McKeon, N., Borras, S.M., 2013. Land grabbing and glob<strong>al</strong> governance:critic<strong>al</strong> perspectives. Glob<strong>al</strong>izations 10 (1), 1–23.Mason, C., Kirkbride, J., Bryde, D., 2007. From stakeholders to institutions: the changingface of soci<strong>al</strong> enterprise governance theory. Manag. Decis. 45 (2), 284–301.McCarthy, J., 2010. Processes of inclusion and adverse incorporation: oil p<strong>al</strong>m andagrarian change in Sumatra, Indonesia. J. Peasant Stud. 37 (4), 821–850.McDermott, M.C., Chan, K.C., 1996. Flexible intelligent relationship management:the business success paradigm in a stakeholder soci<strong>et</strong>y. Learn. Organ. 3 (3), 5–17.McMichael, P., 2013. Land grabbing as security mercantilism in internation<strong>al</strong> relations.Glob<strong>al</strong>izations 10 (1), 47–64.Mehta, L., Veldwisch, G.J., Franco, J., 2012. Introduction to the Speci<strong>al</strong> Issue: WaterGrabbing? Focus on the (Re) appropriation of Finite Water Resources. WaterAlternatives 5 (2), 193–207.Miles, S., 2012. Stakeholder: essenti<strong>al</strong>ly contested or just confused? J. Bus. Ethics108 (3), 285–298.Mitchell, R.K., Agle, B.R., Wood, D.J., 1997. Toward a theory of stakeholder identificationand s<strong>al</strong>ience: defining the principle of who and what re<strong>al</strong>ly counts. Acad.Manag. Rev. 22 (4), 853–886.Mitta, Shepard Daniel with Anuradha, 2009. The Great Land Grab: Rush for World’sFarmland Threatens Food security for the Poor In: Moore M. (Ed.), Oakland, CA94619, USA. The Oakland Institute.Ochieng, J., 2011. Kenya: Dominion Farms Chief Fears for his Life. The Glob<strong>al</strong>Rush for Farm Land and Peoples’ Struggles Against It, Available from:http://farmlandgrab.org/19284 (accessed 09.10.12).Oxfam Internation<strong>al</strong>, 2011. Land and Power Wave Of Investments in Land. OdfamInternation<strong>al</strong>, Oxford, UK.Oya, C., 2013a. M<strong>et</strong>hodologic<strong>al</strong> reflections on ‘land grab’ databases and the ‘landgrab’ literature ‘rush’. J. Peasant Stud. 40 (3), 503–520.Oya, C., 2013b. The land rush and classic agrarian questions of capit<strong>al</strong> and labour: asystematic scoping review of the socioeconomic impact of land grabs in africa.Third World Quarterly 34 (9), 1531–1557.Peluso, N.L., Lund, C., 2011. New frontiers of land control: introduction. J. PeasantStud. 38 (4), 667–681.Pouloudi, A., 1999. Aspects of the stakeholder concept and their implications forinformation systems development. In: Proceedings of the 32nd Hawaii Internation<strong>al</strong>Conference on System Sciences – 1999, Maui, Hawaii, pp. 1–17.Rowley, T.J., 1997. Moving beyond dyadic ties: a n<strong>et</strong>work theory of stakeholderinfluences. Acad. Manag. Rev. 22 (4), 887.Rulli, M.C., D’Odorico, P.D., 2013a. The politics of evidence: a response to Rulli andD’Odorico. J. Peasant Stud. 40 (5), 913–914.Rulli, M.C., D’Odorico, P.D., 2013b. The science of evidence: the v<strong>al</strong>ue of glob<strong>al</strong> studieson land rush. J. Peasant Stud. 40 (5), 907–909.Scoones, I., H<strong>al</strong>l, R., Borras, S., White, B., Wolford, W., 2013. The politics of evidence:m<strong>et</strong>hodologies for understanding the glob<strong>al</strong> land rush. J. Peasant Stud. 40 (3),469–483.Snider, J., Hill, R.P., Martin, D., 2003. Corporate soci<strong>al</strong> responsibility in the 21stcentury: a view from the World’s most successful firms. J. Bus. Ethics 48 (2),175–187.Th<strong>al</strong>er, K., 2013. Large-sc<strong>al</strong>e land acquisitions and soci<strong>al</strong> conflict in Africa. In: InFood Sovereignty: A Critic<strong>al</strong> Di<strong>al</strong>ogue. Internation<strong>al</strong> Conference, Y<strong>al</strong>e University,September 14-15, pp. 1–15.Transnation<strong>al</strong> Institute, 2012. The European Union and the Glob<strong>al</strong> Land Grab, Availablefrom: http://www.tni.org/sites/www.tni.org/files/download/europeanunion and the glob<strong>al</strong> land grab-a5.pdf (accessed 20.10.12).UNCHS, 2001. In: McC<strong>al</strong>lum, D. (Ed.), Tools to Support Participatory Urban DecisionMaking Urban Gove. United Nations Centre for Human S<strong>et</strong>tlements – UNCHS(Habitat), Nairobi.Visser, O., Spoor, M., 2011. Land grabbing in post-Sovi<strong>et</strong> Eurasia: the world’s largestagricultur<strong>al</strong> land reserves at stake. J. Peasant Stud. 38 (2), 299–323.White, B., Borras, S.M., H<strong>al</strong>l, R., Scoones, I., Wolford, W., 2012. The new enclosures:critic<strong>al</strong> perspectives on corporate land de<strong>al</strong>s. J. Peasant Stud. 39 (3–4), 619–647.Wilkinson, J., Reydon, B., Di Sabbato, A., 2012. Concentration and foreign ownershipof land in Brazil in the context of glob<strong>al</strong> land grabbing. Can. J. Dev. Stud./Rev. 33(4), 417–438.Winkler, I., 2009. Stakeholder s<strong>al</strong>ience in corporate codes of <strong>et</strong>hics using legitimacy,power, and urgency to explain stakeholder. Electron. J. Bus. Ethics Organ. Stud.14 (1), 4–13.Wolford, W., Borras, S.M., H<strong>al</strong>l, R., Scoones, I., White, B., 2013. Governing glob<strong>al</strong> landde<strong>al</strong>s: the role of the state in the rush for land. Dev. Change 44 (2), 189–210.World Bank, 2012. World Bank Group Investment Climate Advisory Services – ActivitiesRelated to Land, Annex 2: World Bank Group Statement on Oxfam Report,“Our Land, Our Lives”, Available from: https://www.wbginvestmentclimate.org/donor-partners/upload/2013-IC-FIAS-and-Land.pdf (accessed 03.02.13).Zoomers, A., 2010. Glob<strong>al</strong>isation and the foreignisation of space: seven processesdriving the current glob<strong>al</strong> land grab. J. Peasant Stud. 37 (2), 429–447.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!