12.07.2015 Views

Technology Transfer in the TRIPS Age: - IPRsonline.org

Technology Transfer in the TRIPS Age: - IPRsonline.org

Technology Transfer in the TRIPS Age: - IPRsonline.org

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

May 2009 l ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able DevelopmentICTSD Intellectual Property and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development Series<strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>:The Need for New Types of Partnerships between<strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesBy Dom<strong>in</strong>ique ForayEcole Polytechnique Fédérale de LausanneICTSDIssue Paper No.23


May 2009 l ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development<strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>:The Need for New Types of Partnerships between<strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesBy Dom<strong>in</strong>ique ForayEcole Polytechnique Fédérale de LausanneICTSDIssue Paper No.23


iiDom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesPublished byInternational Centre for Trade and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development (ICTSD)International Environnent House 27 Chem<strong>in</strong> de Balexert, 1219 Geneva, SwitzerlandTel: CH +41 22 917 8492 Fax: +41 22 917 8093E-mail: ictsd@ictsd.chInternet: www.ictsd.<strong>org</strong>Executive Director:Core Team:Ricardo Meléndez-OrtizChristophe Bellmann: Programmes DirectorDavid Vivas-Eugui: Deputy Programmes DirectorAhmed Abdel Latif: Programme Manager, Intellectual PropertyPedro Roffe: Senior Fellow, Intellectual PropertyAcknowledgmentsThe author is grateful for comments and suggestions received from Pedro Roffe as well as for <strong>the</strong> verystimulat<strong>in</strong>g discussions dur<strong>in</strong>g presentations of <strong>the</strong> first and second drafts of <strong>the</strong> paper at various occasions(meet<strong>in</strong>gs of <strong>the</strong> IP Group of <strong>the</strong> Geneva Trade & Development Forum; panel discussion <strong>org</strong>anised byUNCTAD and ICTSD, Palais des Nations, Geneva, 16 June 2008). The author is grateful for <strong>the</strong> support forthis research by <strong>the</strong> ICTSD Programme on Intellectual Property Rights and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development.Support for <strong>the</strong> ICTSD Programme on Intellectual Property Rights and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development hasgenerously been provided by <strong>the</strong> UK Department for International Development (DFID).Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray is Chair <strong>in</strong> Economics and Management of Innovation, Ecole Polytechnique Fédérale deLausanne.For more <strong>in</strong>formation on ICTSD’s Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development, please visit our websiteat http://ictsd.net/programmes/ip/ICTSD welcomes feedback and comments on this document. These can be sent to Ahmed Abdel Latif ataabdellatif@ictsd.chCitation: Foray, Dom<strong>in</strong>ique (2009). <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: <strong>the</strong> Need for New Types ofPartnerships between <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economies. ICTSD Programme on IPRs andSusta<strong>in</strong>able Development, Issue Paper No. 23, International Centre for Trade and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development,Geneva, Switzerland.The views expressed <strong>in</strong> this publication are those of <strong>the</strong> authors and do not necessarily reflect <strong>the</strong> views ofICTSD or <strong>the</strong> fund<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions.Copyright (c) ICTSD, 2009. Readers are encouraged to quote and reproduce this material for educational,non-profit purposes, provided <strong>the</strong> source is acknowledged.This work is licensed under <strong>the</strong> Creative Commons Attribution-Non-commercial-No-Derivative Works 3.0License. To view a copy of this license, visit http://creativecommons.<strong>org</strong>/licenses/by-nc-nd/3.0/ or send aletter to Creative Commons, 171 Second Street, Suite 300, San Francisco, California, 94105, USA.ISSN 1684-9825


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able DevelopmentiiiTABLE OF CONTENTSAcronymsList of Figures, Tables and BoxesForewordExecutive SummaryvviviiixINTRODUCTION 11. OVERVIEW OF MAIN FINDINGS 41.1 – The Economic Fundamentals of <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> to LDCs 41.2 – Current Situation and Key Messages 61.3 – Prioritis<strong>in</strong>g Areas where TT Should be Operated 71.4 – Towards New types of Partnerships 81.5 – Respond<strong>in</strong>g Effectively to <strong>TRIPS</strong> Article 66.2 92. THE NATURE OF TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER 102.1 – Information and Knowledge 102.2 – Consolidation of <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> 132.3 – TT <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Context of LDCs: Capabilities,Organisational Design and Models of Innovation 142.4 – The Choice of <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> Areas<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Case of LDCs 182.5 – Transactional Modes, Barriers and Incentives 202.6 – Brief Summary 263. TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER ANDINTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS 283.1 – The Conditions for <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>to LDCs under <strong>TRIPS</strong> 283.2 – The Impact of <strong>TRIPS</strong> on <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> 293.3 – Markets for <strong>Technology</strong>: Are They Really Efficient? 333.4 – A Fundamental Asymmetry 34


ivDom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economies3.5 – Beyond IPRs: <strong>the</strong> New Knowledge Economy Paradigm 394. CURRENT TRENDS IN TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER 414.1 – The World Bank Framework 414.2 – Virtuous Circles 424.3 – Vicious (or Non Virtuous) Circles: <strong>the</strong> Case of LDCs 435. THE ECONOMICS OF PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPSFOR TECHNOLOGY TRANSFERS BETWEEN DEVELOPEDCOUNTRIES AND LDCS 455.1 – The Economic Rationale of <strong>TRIPS</strong> Article 66.2:<strong>the</strong> Potential and Limitations of Incentives 455.2 – Historical Precedents:Both Incentives and Specialised <strong>Age</strong>nts <strong>in</strong> PPPs Matter 475.3 – Public-Private Partnerships for <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> 515.4 – Effectiveness Conditions: Appropriate Donor Assistance 535.5 – Draw<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>TRIPS</strong> Council Country Reports underArticle 66.2 50Conclusion 56ENDNOTES 57REFERENCES 59


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able DevelopmentvABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMSFDI: Foreign Direct InvestmentGPT: General Purpose TechnologiesICTs: Information and Communication TechnologiesIPRs: Intellectual Property RightsLDCs: Least Developed CountriesMNCs: Mult<strong>in</strong>ational CorporationsODA: Overseas Development AssistancePPPs: Public-private Partnerships<strong>TRIPS</strong>: Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property RightsTT: <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>WIPO: World Intellectual Property OrganisationWTO: World Trade Organisation


viDom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesLIST OF FIGURES, TABLES AND BOXESLIST OF FIGURES1 – The Growth of Royalties and Licens<strong>in</strong>g Fees 252 – Patent Applications <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> LDCs, Residents vs.Non-residents, 1995-2002 363 – Positive Feedback Systems, Virtuous and Vicious Processes 424 – Functions and Role of a PPP as TT Operator 485 – Global and Local Demand and <strong>the</strong> Need for SpecialIncentives for Local Entrepreneurs 506 – Projects Targeted by an Optimal Government-IndustryTT Programme 52LIST OF TABLES1 – A Typology of TT as an Economic Operation 62 – Mapp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Areas for TT Focus 203 – Costs and Benefits of a Stronger Patent System 354 – Patent Applications by Residents and Non-residents <strong>in</strong> LDCs 365 – Mapp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>s Documented <strong>in</strong> a Country Report:A Real Example 55LIST OF BOXES1 – Knowledge as a Commodity 112 – Cleaner Production Centres as an Example of a <strong>Technology</strong> Platform 163 – Def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Areas of Focus: Six Arguments 184 – <strong>TRIPS</strong> and <strong>the</strong> Public Doma<strong>in</strong> of Knowledge 29


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able DevelopmentviiFOREWORD<strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnerships between <strong>the</strong>Least Developed and Most Advanced Economies is a recent contribution of <strong>the</strong> ICTSD Programmeon Intellectual Property Rights and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development. <strong>Technology</strong> transfer (TT) todevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries has been discussed by <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational community and policy makers <strong>in</strong>general for more than three decades and cont<strong>in</strong>ues to resurface <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational deliberations.In recent years, ICTSD has contributed to <strong>the</strong>se discussions by produc<strong>in</strong>g some pioneer<strong>in</strong>gstudies. 1This study draws on <strong>the</strong> empirical literature address<strong>in</strong>g TT issues <strong>in</strong> an age where <strong>the</strong> trend ofre<strong>in</strong>forc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> protection and enforcement of <strong>in</strong>tellectual property rights (IPRs) prevails. Ithighlights <strong>the</strong> complexity of <strong>the</strong> TT process particularly when entities at different developmentlevels are <strong>in</strong>volved and <strong>the</strong> importance, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se cases, of <strong>the</strong> absorptive capacity of <strong>the</strong>recipient firms. The study also exam<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong> arguments advanced to consider <strong>in</strong>tellectualproperty (IP) protection as both a h<strong>in</strong>drance and a stimulus to TT. The paper makes practicalrecommendations, applicable, first, to least developed countries (LDCs), that want to use TTsas an effective growth eng<strong>in</strong>e, and, second, to developed countries that have to comply with<strong>the</strong> provisions of Article 66.2 of <strong>the</strong> World Trade Organisation (WTO) Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (<strong>TRIPS</strong>).Accord<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> study, many countries are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir exposure to foreign technologiesby means of trade and foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestment (FDI), while improv<strong>in</strong>g absorptive capacitiesto facilitate <strong>the</strong> dissem<strong>in</strong>ation of technologies and spillovers with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> domestic economy.This represents a virtuous path that a number of develop<strong>in</strong>g countries – notably middle-<strong>in</strong>comecountries – follow. The experience of LDCs, however, is less promis<strong>in</strong>g. Firstly, FDI and traderema<strong>in</strong> at a low level and <strong>the</strong> poor quality of <strong>the</strong>ir absorptive capacities makes it unlikely that<strong>the</strong> few foreign technologies that are transferred will dissem<strong>in</strong>ate throughout <strong>the</strong> economy. Inthis respect, <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> message is that <strong>the</strong> number, scale and doma<strong>in</strong>s of TTs cannot be left todepend on FDI or trade, nor can <strong>the</strong>y take only <strong>the</strong> form of market transactions (licences).With respect to <strong>TRIPS</strong> Article 66.2 obligations, <strong>the</strong> study suggests that transfer of technologyshould be part of a pr<strong>in</strong>cipal economic operation and not be a jo<strong>in</strong>t product or by-product,cont<strong>in</strong>gent on o<strong>the</strong>r operations. The locus of decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g regard<strong>in</strong>g modes of learn<strong>in</strong>g andareas for focus must shift away from foreign bodies to local agents and authorities. As faras additional <strong>in</strong>centives by governments are concerned, <strong>the</strong>y should consist of assistance forprojects that are socially beneficial but with low expected profitability for technology supplierfirms. This should ensure that conditions for TT <strong>in</strong>volve <strong>the</strong> choice of relevant partners on both<strong>the</strong> supply and demand sides, selection of <strong>the</strong> right area related to a clearly expressed localdemand for technology and <strong>the</strong> creation of <strong>org</strong>anisational forms that favour <strong>the</strong> consolidationof <strong>the</strong> transfer (absorption, adaptation and subsequent spillover), as well as <strong>the</strong> relatedentrepreneurial dynamic.In this context, <strong>the</strong> study advances <strong>the</strong> need for greater use of public-private partnerships(PPPs) as a mechanism for ensur<strong>in</strong>g both <strong>the</strong> effectiveness of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>tervention and <strong>the</strong> efficiencyof <strong>the</strong> TT operation.The premise of ICTSD’s work <strong>in</strong> this field is based on <strong>the</strong> appreciation that IPRs are economicallyand politically important but controversial, and towards that end a better understand<strong>in</strong>g of IP is<strong>in</strong>dispensable for <strong>in</strong>formed policy mak<strong>in</strong>g at <strong>the</strong> national and <strong>in</strong>ternational level. The relationshipbetween transfer of technology and IP stands high today <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> deliberations of <strong>the</strong> Council for<strong>TRIPS</strong>, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> discussions of <strong>the</strong> UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) and <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> implementation of <strong>the</strong> WIPO Development <strong>Age</strong>nda recommendations adopted <strong>in</strong> 2007.


viiiDom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesEmpirical evidence on <strong>the</strong> role of IP protection <strong>in</strong> promot<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>novation and dissem<strong>in</strong>ation ofknowledge rema<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>conclusive. Diverg<strong>in</strong>g views persist on <strong>the</strong>se matters. However, <strong>the</strong>re isa consensus that IP matters and that <strong>the</strong> right policies and friendly environments are neededto gear <strong>the</strong> system to achieve its fundamental objectives: namely, to promote <strong>in</strong>novation andcreativity and facilitate <strong>the</strong> dissem<strong>in</strong>ation of knowledge.A central objective of <strong>the</strong> ICTSD Programme on Intellectual Property and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Developmenthas been to facilitate <strong>the</strong> emergence of a critical mass of well-<strong>in</strong>formed stakeholders <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries – <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g decision makers and negotiators, but also with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> privatesector and civil society – who will be able to def<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong>ir own susta<strong>in</strong>able human developmentobjectives and effectively advance <strong>the</strong>m at <strong>the</strong> national and <strong>in</strong>ternational levels.We hope you will f<strong>in</strong>d this study an additional contribution to <strong>the</strong> debate on IP, <strong>in</strong>novation andsusta<strong>in</strong>able development, and particularly <strong>in</strong> respond<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> need for <strong>in</strong>creased awarenessand better understand<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> complexities of technology transfer and, among o<strong>the</strong>rs, its<strong>in</strong>terface with IP. An underly<strong>in</strong>g assumption of our work has been <strong>the</strong> pursuit of a proper balancebetween <strong>the</strong> different <strong>in</strong>terests at stake <strong>in</strong> design<strong>in</strong>g appropriate IP regimes compliant with<strong>in</strong>ternational commitments and supportive of public policy objectives as well as developmentefforts.Ricardo Meléndez-OrtizChief Executive, ICTSD


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able DevelopmentixExecutive SummaryThis study draws on <strong>the</strong> abundant empirical literature produced over recent decades that addresses<strong>the</strong> issues of technology transfer (TT) between countries with very different development levels <strong>in</strong> anage of stronger <strong>in</strong>tellectual property (IP) regimes.The key f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs of this study are that, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of least developed countries (LDCs), <strong>the</strong> number,scale and doma<strong>in</strong>s of TT cannot depend alone on general economic operations, such as foreign direct<strong>in</strong>vestment (FDI) or <strong>in</strong>frastructure construction; nei<strong>the</strong>r can <strong>the</strong>y only take <strong>the</strong> form of markettransactions (licences). In all <strong>the</strong>se cases, <strong>the</strong> particular circumstances and conditions that prevail <strong>in</strong>LDCs imply a suboptimal level of TT <strong>in</strong> relation to <strong>the</strong>se countries’ needs.There is <strong>the</strong>refore an obvious economic rationality for specific projects <strong>in</strong> which <strong>the</strong> TT is <strong>the</strong> primaryproduct (an economic project <strong>in</strong> itself, not l<strong>in</strong>ked with ano<strong>the</strong>r economic operation) but entails alow expected private profitability for <strong>the</strong> technology-own<strong>in</strong>g firm. Such a prospect would <strong>in</strong>volveacknowledg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> existence of TT operations with far smaller commercial returns or no commercialreturn at all and f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g operational mechanisms to <strong>in</strong>centivise <strong>the</strong>se firms to s<strong>in</strong>k costs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>seoperations. Such a strategy requires <strong>the</strong> provision of additional <strong>in</strong>centives from governments ofdeveloped countries.Incentivis<strong>in</strong>g foreign firms to enter such transactions is a clear opportunity for developed countrygovernments to properly fulfil <strong>the</strong>ir obligations conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> Article 66.2 of <strong>the</strong> World Trade Organisation(WTO) Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (<strong>TRIPS</strong>). The follow<strong>in</strong>grecommendations are applicable to developed countries’ <strong>TRIPS</strong> obligations:• The transfer of technology should form <strong>the</strong> subject of a pr<strong>in</strong>cipal economic operation (andnot be a jo<strong>in</strong>t product or by-product; i.e. cont<strong>in</strong>gent on o<strong>the</strong>r operations);• The locus of decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g regard<strong>in</strong>g modes of learn<strong>in</strong>g and areas for focus must shiftaway from foreign bodies to local agents and authorities;• In provid<strong>in</strong>g additional <strong>in</strong>centives to <strong>the</strong> technology-own<strong>in</strong>g firms, governments should seekeffectiveness and efficiency. To achieve this:- Governments should provide <strong>in</strong>centives <strong>in</strong> an effective way by only assist<strong>in</strong>g projectsthat are socially beneficial but not very profitable for <strong>the</strong> firms that own and couldtransfer <strong>the</strong> technology; and- Conditions for <strong>the</strong> efficiency of <strong>the</strong> TT operations <strong>in</strong>volve <strong>the</strong> choice of relevantpartners both on supply and demand sides, selection of <strong>the</strong> right area for focus (relatedto a clearly expressed local demand for technology) and <strong>the</strong> creation of <strong>org</strong>anisationalforms that will favour <strong>the</strong> consolidation of <strong>the</strong> transfer (absorption, adaptation andsubsequent spillovers), as well as <strong>the</strong> related entrepreneurial dynamic;• Governments should make as much use as possible of public-private partnerships (PPPs) as amechanism for ensur<strong>in</strong>g both <strong>the</strong> effectiveness of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>tervention and <strong>the</strong> efficiency of <strong>the</strong>TT operation.<strong>Technology</strong> transfers have to be operated <strong>in</strong> many doma<strong>in</strong>s (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g export-oriented <strong>in</strong>dustry). But<strong>the</strong>y must be particularly supported <strong>in</strong> those doma<strong>in</strong>s that correspond to <strong>the</strong> model of <strong>in</strong>novationcentral to economic growth <strong>in</strong> LDCs: that is, entrepreneurial activities meet<strong>in</strong>g needs <strong>in</strong> local marketsthat are likely to generate domestic spillovers. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, TTs must offer a positive supply


xDom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economiesresponse to a demand for technology stemm<strong>in</strong>g from local entrepreneurs. Two factors are relevan<strong>the</strong>re:1. These doma<strong>in</strong>s are potentially important for growth because <strong>the</strong> spillovers generated <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>course of such projects are likely to be captured by <strong>the</strong> local economy; and2. These doma<strong>in</strong>s need additional <strong>in</strong>centives so <strong>the</strong> donor’s <strong>in</strong>tervention will be effective andrespond fully to <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> provision, which is not necessarily <strong>the</strong> case of export-orientedsectors <strong>in</strong> which <strong>the</strong> market <strong>in</strong>centives alone are sufficiently strong to motivate firms <strong>in</strong> richcountries to operate TTs.The o<strong>the</strong>r areas – for <strong>in</strong>stance <strong>the</strong> export goods-oriented manufactur<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g sectors – arealso important but <strong>the</strong>y will <strong>in</strong> any case be served through TTs operat<strong>in</strong>g as jo<strong>in</strong>t products of FDI. Assuch, <strong>the</strong>y should not be listed as part of <strong>the</strong> efforts made by <strong>the</strong> developed countries to comply withArticle 66.2 of <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> Agreement.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development1INTRODUCTIONThe broad and rapid diffusion of new andadvanced knowledge is positive for social wellbe<strong>in</strong>g.Efficiency and growth are promotedby <strong>the</strong> speed with which new knowledge and<strong>in</strong>novative technologies are dissem<strong>in</strong>ated: <strong>the</strong>greater <strong>the</strong> proportion of <strong>in</strong>dividuals, firms, orcountries mak<strong>in</strong>g swift use of superior productsand processes ra<strong>the</strong>r than be<strong>in</strong>g restricted to<strong>in</strong>ferior substitutes, <strong>the</strong> more widespread andsubstantial <strong>the</strong> growth benefits. If, for <strong>in</strong>stance,only one firm (or one country) uses a newtechnology that <strong>in</strong>creases productivity whileo<strong>the</strong>r firms (or countries) are obliged to reta<strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> old, less efficient technique, <strong>the</strong> benefitsare significantly less than if all firms were ableto adopt <strong>the</strong> new technology. This dissem<strong>in</strong>ationis important for <strong>the</strong> efficiency of <strong>the</strong> economicgrowth process.One of <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> forms of knowledge dissem<strong>in</strong>ation(and probably <strong>the</strong> most valuable from <strong>the</strong> po<strong>in</strong>tof view of develop<strong>in</strong>g productive and <strong>in</strong>novativecapabilities) is technology transfer (TT). Krugman(1979), for <strong>in</strong>stance, considers <strong>the</strong> pattern oftrade and economic growth to be governedprimarily by two activities: <strong>in</strong>novation and TT.Early literature based on <strong>the</strong> standard modelof economic growth predicted convergenceacross countries and considered TT as an “easy”mechanism to achieve this process. Once produced,technology can be widely applied. Theimplicit assumption is that <strong>the</strong> cost of technologydiffusion is lower than that of its production.However, on <strong>the</strong> ground, <strong>the</strong> difficulties andcomplexity of TT operations, particularly when<strong>the</strong>y <strong>in</strong>volve two countries different levels ofdevelopment, has been recognised <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>grow<strong>in</strong>g literature on <strong>in</strong>ternational technologytransfer. Some of <strong>the</strong> landmarks towards a betterunderstand<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> difficulties and complexityof TT <strong>in</strong>clude:• A more adequate conceptualisation oftechnology (stress<strong>in</strong>g its tacit dimension);• A careful appreciation of <strong>the</strong> transactionaldifficulties particularly related to problemsof contract<strong>in</strong>g tacit knowledge and pric<strong>in</strong>gtechnologies on markets that rema<strong>in</strong>relatively <strong>in</strong>efficient <strong>in</strong> this respect;• A better understand<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> importance(and non-trivial nature) of diffusion with<strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> country once a technology has beentransferred <strong>the</strong>re. This is a process that<strong>in</strong>volves particular barriers and <strong>in</strong>centives;• The grow<strong>in</strong>g consideration of <strong>the</strong> fact that<strong>in</strong>novation and technological progress <strong>in</strong>LDCs cannot be a mere reproduction ofwhat is happen<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> developed countries.Innovations must be tailored accord<strong>in</strong>gto local opportunities, capabilities andneeds. Their consequences for economicdevelopment are strongly dependent onhow such “particularisation” materialises<strong>in</strong> products, processes and services;• The recognition that <strong>the</strong> most important<strong>in</strong>novations for LDCs are probably not“technical” but reside <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> process ofdiscover<strong>in</strong>g a country’s strength; and• An accumulation of evidence concern<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> relative advantages and shortcom<strong>in</strong>gsof <strong>the</strong> different channels through which TToccurs.These landmarks towards a better understand<strong>in</strong>gof TT, <strong>the</strong> conditions for its success and how tom<strong>in</strong>imise <strong>the</strong> risks of failure, have not, however,given rise to new policy opportunities and <strong>the</strong>implementation of new programmes.In parallel, <strong>the</strong> knowledge economy has beenestablished slowly <strong>in</strong> rich countries, stronglyaffect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> relative importance of <strong>the</strong> various TTchannels. And while <strong>the</strong> market for technologiesas a prom<strong>in</strong>ent mechanism has grown over <strong>the</strong>last two decades, this has possibly come at <strong>the</strong>expense of non-market based mechanisms, suchas imitation.This study draws on <strong>the</strong> abundant empiricalliterature on TT produced over recent decades.


2 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesAfter an overview of <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs of <strong>the</strong>paper <strong>in</strong> chapter 1, chapter 2 expands on <strong>the</strong> ideaof <strong>the</strong> cognitive complexity of TT based on <strong>the</strong>dist<strong>in</strong>ction between knowledge and <strong>in</strong>formation.It <strong>the</strong>n exam<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong> different phases that make upthis complexity. It discusses how this complexitybecomes even greater when <strong>the</strong> transfer <strong>in</strong>volvesentities of very different development levels anddemonstrates <strong>the</strong> pivotal nature, <strong>in</strong> this case, of<strong>the</strong> notion of capabilities. The build<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong>secapabilities is carried out with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> framework ofsuitable <strong>org</strong>anisational forms, such as technologyplatforms or production centres. This section<strong>the</strong>n elaborates on a concept of <strong>in</strong>cremental<strong>in</strong>novation oriented towards <strong>the</strong> development oflocal applications – a concept that should help tostructure <strong>the</strong> objectives of TTs made to LDCs.Chapter 2 also raises <strong>the</strong> question of <strong>the</strong> choicesof specialised doma<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> which to undertakeTTs. It makes reference to <strong>the</strong> work by Enos<strong>in</strong> particular to show how choices that areirrelevant, unconsidered and guided by donorscan lead to catastrophic results. It suggests <strong>the</strong>importance of <strong>the</strong> process of discover<strong>in</strong>g goodspecialisations, as effectively demonstratedby <strong>the</strong> works of Hausman and Rodrik; <strong>in</strong>deed,technologies from <strong>in</strong>dustrialised countries veryoften require complex and costly adaptations,with an uncerta<strong>in</strong> degree of success. Learn<strong>in</strong>gwhat a country is good at produc<strong>in</strong>g is <strong>the</strong>reforea critical issue and requires entrepreneurialcommitments. The knowledge that is likely tobe generated from <strong>the</strong>se “experiments” is ofgreat social value. F<strong>in</strong>ally, chapter 2 tackles<strong>the</strong> question of barriers and <strong>in</strong>centives offeredto firms to undertake TT operations and carry<strong>the</strong>m through successfully. These <strong>in</strong>centives andbarriers are exam<strong>in</strong>ed for different forms of TTs(ma<strong>in</strong> product, jo<strong>in</strong>t product and by-product).Chapter 3 deals with <strong>the</strong> role of <strong>in</strong>tellectualproperty <strong>in</strong> TTs. Recently, <strong>the</strong> number of transfersbased on licence purchas<strong>in</strong>g has <strong>in</strong>creasedconsiderably. This must be correlated with <strong>the</strong>globalization of IP systems and <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gpower of technology markets. This part of <strong>the</strong>text summarises <strong>the</strong> arguments that po<strong>in</strong>t to anegative role of IP protection and those that,on <strong>the</strong> contrary, <strong>in</strong>dicate a positive role. InChapter 3, <strong>the</strong> question of <strong>the</strong> effects and generalimpact of <strong>TRIPS</strong> on technological <strong>in</strong>novation <strong>in</strong>LDCs is also dealt with. The development of aglobal IP system, correspond<strong>in</strong>g to uniform qualitystandards has, without a doubt, positive effectson rich countries. It makes extremely uncerta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>vestments more secure, encourages betterknowledge dissem<strong>in</strong>ation via <strong>the</strong> market and givesgreater visibility to <strong>in</strong>novation efforts and <strong>the</strong>accumulation of <strong>in</strong>tellectual assets, especially <strong>in</strong>small firms. These positive effects <strong>in</strong>disputablycompensate for <strong>the</strong> social cost imposed bymonopoly prices <strong>in</strong> a system that is function<strong>in</strong>g“reasonably” well. However, <strong>the</strong>se positiveeffects can under no circumstances be predicted<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> context of <strong>in</strong>ternational TTs betweencountries with very different development levels.In this particular case, <strong>the</strong> new system takes <strong>the</strong>place of a previous system based on imitation,without replac<strong>in</strong>g it completely. A comparativelyimportant TT channel disappears; o<strong>the</strong>rs takeits place but also stipulate different rules lessfavourable to LDCs.Chapter 4 takes stock of <strong>the</strong> most recent evidenceabout TT and technology diffusion as compiledby <strong>the</strong> World Bank (2008). It draws on this datato observe that middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries are<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly successful <strong>in</strong> us<strong>in</strong>g FDI and trade tooperate TTs (TT hav<strong>in</strong>g clearly <strong>the</strong> status of ajo<strong>in</strong>t product) and that due to <strong>the</strong> improvementof <strong>the</strong>ir absorptive capacities, those TTs generatespillovers to <strong>the</strong> domestic economy result<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>crease of its overall efficiency. Whenth<strong>in</strong>gs are go<strong>in</strong>g well <strong>in</strong> this way, one may standback <strong>in</strong> awe at <strong>the</strong> unfold<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> process andits ability to susta<strong>in</strong> high marg<strong>in</strong>al social andprivate returns on TTs over an extended periodof time. But this is occurr<strong>in</strong>g far less <strong>in</strong> LDCsand evidence shows that trade and FDI rema<strong>in</strong>at a low level. Thus <strong>the</strong> success of TT as jo<strong>in</strong>tproduct is poorly supported <strong>in</strong> LDCs, while weakabsorptive capacities prevent <strong>the</strong> few TTs thatdo take place from lead<strong>in</strong>g to spillovers <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong>domestic economy.F<strong>in</strong>ally, chapter 5 develops a TT model that<strong>in</strong>corporates <strong>the</strong> different elements consideredto provide general practical recom-mendations,first to LDCs that want to effectively use TTs


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development3as a growth eng<strong>in</strong>e, and second to developedcountries that have to comply with <strong>the</strong>provisions of <strong>TRIPS</strong> Article 66.2. This segmentfirst exam<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong> conditions for implementationof <strong>TRIPS</strong> Article 66.2, which encourages firms <strong>in</strong>rich countries to transfer technologies to LDCs.Here, <strong>the</strong> pert<strong>in</strong>ence of <strong>the</strong> objective (<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>centives) is shown and, through <strong>the</strong> use ofrecent examples, suggests that under certa<strong>in</strong>conditions private firms can “respond” positivelyto an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives – <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of orphanand neglected diseases, for <strong>in</strong>stance. Success <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong>se areas (expressed as <strong>the</strong> commitment ofprivate firms to activities considered a prioriunprofitable) is apparently not carried over to<strong>the</strong> transfer of technology to LDCs however.Chapter 5 thus attempts to expla<strong>in</strong> this absenceand to outl<strong>in</strong>e some rudimentary solutions,<strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> use of PPPs as a mechanism to<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>the</strong> efficiency of TT operations, as wellas <strong>the</strong> careful selection of areas to ensure <strong>the</strong>effectiveness of aid from <strong>in</strong>ternational donors(<strong>in</strong>centives should be provided where and when<strong>the</strong>y are really needed).


4 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economies1. OVERVIEW OF MAIN FINDINGS1.1 The Economic Fundamentals of <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> to LDCs<strong>Technology</strong> transfer basically consists of a“transfer” of technological knowledge, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>ga “transfer” of <strong>the</strong> capacity to assimilate,implement and develop a technology. Theacquisition of <strong>in</strong>formation concern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>technology is thus only a part – althoughadmittedly an important one – of <strong>the</strong> transfer.The process of learn<strong>in</strong>g how to use andma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> technology is at least as importantas its frequently required adaptation to localconditions. Ultimately, this adaptation may leadto <strong>the</strong> development of new applications basedon <strong>the</strong> transferred technology. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, atechnology is itself progressive; <strong>the</strong>refore, <strong>the</strong>challenge of a TT is to master technologies thatare chang<strong>in</strong>g cont<strong>in</strong>uously. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>the</strong> perimeterfor potential adopters of <strong>the</strong> transferredtechnology is never predeterm<strong>in</strong>ed and <strong>the</strong>transfer’s social returns depend essentially on<strong>the</strong> extension of this perimeter beyond <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>itial target – for example, a specific <strong>in</strong>dustrial<strong>in</strong>stallation. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong> transferprocess should not stop at <strong>the</strong> first <strong>in</strong>stallationbut with <strong>the</strong> generalisation of <strong>the</strong> technology <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> geographical space considered.Thus a successful TT goes through <strong>the</strong> perilousphases of <strong>the</strong> assimilation and absorptionof technological knowledge: adaptation tolocal conditions, absorption of subsequentimprovements and generalisation of <strong>the</strong>transferred knowledge. These phases are describedas <strong>the</strong> consolidation of <strong>the</strong> transfer. Thiscomplex cognitive dimension of TT demandsan equivalent level of complexity of <strong>the</strong><strong>org</strong>anisational forms related to <strong>the</strong> transferprocess. The latter must guarantee not only<strong>the</strong> acquisition of <strong>in</strong>formation but also <strong>the</strong>learn<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> technology, its adaptation andits progression. Favourable <strong>org</strong>anisationalconditions can also promote its generalisation.It is <strong>in</strong> accordance with this logic that <strong>the</strong>efficiency of <strong>the</strong> various transfer modes can beevaluated.The TT context between systems with verydifferent development levels makes <strong>the</strong>problems of TT consolidation (absorption andlearn<strong>in</strong>g, adaptation, assimilation of subsequentimprovements, generalisation) even moredifficult to solve. Such heterogeneities create“capabilities’ issues.” Weak capabilities on <strong>the</strong>LDC side impose strong forms of <strong>in</strong>ternal andexternal <strong>org</strong>anisation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> LDC to maximise<strong>the</strong> probability of succeed<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> variousphases of TT. Weak capabilities also imply that<strong>the</strong> various modes of TT are not “equivalent”<strong>in</strong> terms of <strong>the</strong>ir potential to impact <strong>the</strong>productivity of a wide range of sectors <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>local economy.As far as LDCs are concerned, this studyemphasises <strong>the</strong> centrality of a particular modelof <strong>in</strong>novation for growth and development.Research and development (R&D) and o<strong>the</strong>rmore <strong>in</strong>formal learn<strong>in</strong>g activities undertaken toproduce locally oriented <strong>in</strong>novations, allow <strong>the</strong>country to develop absorptive capacity, whileat <strong>the</strong> same time <strong>the</strong> locally generated spilloverfrom this same R&D may end up diffus<strong>in</strong>g awayfrom <strong>the</strong> local economy. There are vast areas ofeconomic activity where <strong>in</strong>novation is neededto serve local needs and local demand, whereby“local” may mean a large fraction of <strong>the</strong> worldpopulation.Economically speak<strong>in</strong>g, it makes sense to knowwhe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> TT constitutes an economicoperation <strong>in</strong> itself or is dependent on aneconomic operation that exceeds it. In thisrespect, a dist<strong>in</strong>ction will be made between:• <strong>Transfer</strong>s dependent on more generaleconomic operations, such as foreign direct<strong>in</strong>vestment (FDI), <strong>the</strong> construction andsupply of <strong>in</strong>frastructure, or <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>tegrationof companies from develop<strong>in</strong>g countries asexporters <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational trade. In anyevent, <strong>the</strong> TT is a jo<strong>in</strong>t product or byproduct;2 <strong>the</strong> importance and quality ofTTs are <strong>the</strong>refore cont<strong>in</strong>gent on a largenumber of factors result<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>the</strong>primary economic operation. It is thus<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives for <strong>the</strong> primary economic


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development5operation to succeed that determ<strong>in</strong>ewhe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> TT and its consolidation alsosucceed (or not);• <strong>Transfer</strong>s that <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>mselves constitute<strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> operation. This is carried outei<strong>the</strong>r through <strong>the</strong> medium of <strong>the</strong> market(licence, jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures), or via nonmarketchannels. In <strong>the</strong>se cases, <strong>the</strong> primemotivation for <strong>the</strong> operation is <strong>the</strong> successof <strong>the</strong> TT and it is <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives directlyl<strong>in</strong>ked to <strong>the</strong> TT (cost and profit) thatcommand <strong>the</strong> operation.When TT is a jo<strong>in</strong>t product of FDI, <strong>the</strong> locusof decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g lies <strong>in</strong> foreign firms. Foreignfirms decide <strong>the</strong> modes of learn<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>the</strong> amountof resources devoted to <strong>the</strong> TT operation, <strong>the</strong>potential scope for fur<strong>the</strong>r dissem<strong>in</strong>ation,and <strong>the</strong> objectives of assimilat<strong>in</strong>g subsequentimprovements. The choice of <strong>the</strong> doma<strong>in</strong> where<strong>the</strong> TT will operate is pre-def<strong>in</strong>ed when <strong>the</strong> TTis a jo<strong>in</strong>t or a by-product. Draw<strong>in</strong>g on Enos et al.(1998), this paper proceeds to argue that when<strong>the</strong> locus of decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g for TTs lies with<strong>the</strong> foreign firms, <strong>the</strong>re is a risk of suboptimaldecision processes.When <strong>the</strong> TT is <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> operation, <strong>the</strong>re ismore flexibility about who will make <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>decisions: i.e., domestic bodies (entrepreneurs,governmental agencies), foreign donors or foreignfirms. For <strong>in</strong>stance, when <strong>the</strong> TT is <strong>the</strong>ma<strong>in</strong> operation, <strong>the</strong> question of <strong>the</strong> choiceof doma<strong>in</strong>s (who makes <strong>the</strong> choice, based onwhat criteria, how to go about discover<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>“best” doma<strong>in</strong>s, etc.) becomes an <strong>in</strong>tegralpart of <strong>the</strong> economic issue of TT. This aspectis crucial – <strong>the</strong> choice of where TTs will operatematters a great deal. TTs operate <strong>in</strong> specialiseddoma<strong>in</strong>s that <strong>the</strong>y will streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>in</strong> order totransform <strong>the</strong>m <strong>in</strong>to a growth eng<strong>in</strong>e for <strong>the</strong>relevant country. Enos et al. (1998) made thisargument well, stat<strong>in</strong>g that: “<strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> task<strong>in</strong> advanc<strong>in</strong>g science and technology <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries is to identify <strong>the</strong> mostattractive direction <strong>in</strong> which to proceed. Thisproper direction is that which best represents<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terests of <strong>the</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries andthis <strong>in</strong>terest is not congruent with <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terestsof banks or foreign donors.”It is <strong>the</strong>refore apparent that <strong>the</strong> technologyholder’s commitment may vary considerablydepend<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> TT’s status as an economicoperation and <strong>the</strong> importance attributed to it <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> success of <strong>the</strong> primary operation (if it doesitself not constitute <strong>the</strong> primary operation).When <strong>the</strong> TT is a jo<strong>in</strong>t product (occurr<strong>in</strong>g asa consequence of a direct <strong>in</strong>vestment), and ifth<strong>in</strong>gs are go<strong>in</strong>g well, <strong>the</strong> phases of absorption,adaptation, and assimilation of subsequentimprovements are <strong>in</strong> a sense “embedded” <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment plan. However, s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> TTis a jo<strong>in</strong>t product, <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>the</strong> problem of“balanc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>centives” between <strong>the</strong> need tomake <strong>the</strong> direct <strong>in</strong>vestment operational andprofitable <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> short-term, and <strong>the</strong> need totransfer technologies and capabilities. Indeed,<strong>the</strong> risk of a strong imbalance aris<strong>in</strong>g between<strong>the</strong>se two <strong>in</strong>centives is considerable <strong>in</strong> LDCss<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> cost of transferr<strong>in</strong>g technologies andbuild<strong>in</strong>g capabilities is very high. As a result,<strong>the</strong> foreign firm is tempted to limit <strong>the</strong> scopeand depth of <strong>the</strong> transfer of technologies andcapabilities <strong>in</strong> order to <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>the</strong> shorttermprofitability of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment. In such acase, <strong>the</strong> TT is no longer a jo<strong>in</strong>t product butbecomes a by-product – that is, a negligibleobjective.When TT is <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> operation, <strong>the</strong> problemis that <strong>in</strong>centives cannot be allowed to dependon ano<strong>the</strong>r economic operation; <strong>the</strong> TT must besufficiently attractive <strong>in</strong> itself for <strong>the</strong> technologyholder to enter <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> transaction. In thiscase, operational mechanisms must <strong>in</strong>centivisetechnology-own<strong>in</strong>g firms to s<strong>in</strong>k costs <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong>seoperations. In addition, classes of firms likely toserve as effective partners <strong>in</strong> such transactionsneed to be specifically targeted. This <strong>in</strong>cludes,for example, <strong>in</strong>dependent and specialiseddevelopers and suppliers of technologicalprocesses and solutions.The table below summarises <strong>the</strong> economiccharacteristics of TTs as ma<strong>in</strong>, jo<strong>in</strong>t- and byproducts.


8 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economieshigh for motivat<strong>in</strong>g foreign firms to commitresources; and• Doma<strong>in</strong>s where <strong>the</strong>re is a clear demand fortechnology from local entrepreneurs, whoare <strong>the</strong>n <strong>in</strong>centivised to develop <strong>in</strong>novativeprojects to suit local needs and markets.These projects are likely to generatespillover effects that are more easilycaptured by <strong>the</strong> local economy than thosegenerated through FDI and <strong>the</strong> productionof knowledge for global markets.In summary, prioritisation done as a responseto <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> 66.2 provision should emphasisethose doma<strong>in</strong>s correspond<strong>in</strong>g to a certa<strong>in</strong>model of <strong>in</strong>novation that is central to LDCs.This <strong>in</strong>cludes, for <strong>in</strong>stance, locally oriented<strong>in</strong>novations that address local needs throughlocal entrepreneurial activities, which allow<strong>the</strong> country to develop absorptive capacities.These doma<strong>in</strong>s are important for growthbecause <strong>the</strong> spillover generated <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> courseof such projects is likely to be captured by<strong>the</strong> local economy. Additionally, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>sedoma<strong>in</strong>s, TTs need additional <strong>in</strong>centives so<strong>the</strong> donor’s <strong>in</strong>tervention will be effective andrespond fully to <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> provision, which isnot necessarily <strong>the</strong> case for export-orientedsectors <strong>in</strong> which <strong>the</strong> market <strong>in</strong>centives aloneare sufficiently strong to motivate firms <strong>in</strong>rich countries to operate TTs. O<strong>the</strong>r areas,such as export-oriented goods process<strong>in</strong>g andmanufactur<strong>in</strong>g, are also important but do notneed additional <strong>in</strong>centives. Also, TTs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>sedoma<strong>in</strong>s are likely to generate less spilloverbecause of asymmetric capabilities betweenmult<strong>in</strong>ational corporations (MNCs) and <strong>the</strong>rest of <strong>the</strong> economy. As such, <strong>the</strong>y should notbe listed as part of <strong>the</strong> efforts made by <strong>the</strong>developed countries to comply with <strong>the</strong> 66.2provision.1.4 Towards New Types of PartnershipsThe complexity and difficulties of TT operationscall for new types of public-private partnerships(PPP). The essence of this k<strong>in</strong>d of arrangementresides <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>volvement of a third party, whichis specialised <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g public donors, privatefirms, and local entrepreneurial activities toensure <strong>the</strong> effectiveness of <strong>the</strong> TT operation.As such, this process will compensate for <strong>the</strong>shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs of exist<strong>in</strong>g mechanisms and whichare essential to address problems aris<strong>in</strong>g fromTT management as a ma<strong>in</strong> operation.As stated above, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> circumstances of TT asa ma<strong>in</strong> operation, <strong>the</strong> locus of decision-mak<strong>in</strong>gshould not be kept <strong>in</strong> foreign assistance bodiesbut ra<strong>the</strong>r transferred to local government<strong>in</strong>itiatives and entrepreneurs. Shift<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>locus of decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g to local actors andauthorities is part of PPPs’ menu of tasks.The PPP has to work on <strong>the</strong> supply and demandside. In both cases, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive issue (i.e. tomotivate local entrepreneurs and technologyholders) has to be addressed.On <strong>the</strong> demand side, <strong>the</strong> centrality of<strong>in</strong>novations target<strong>in</strong>g local needs and potentiallygenerat<strong>in</strong>g spillover that is capturedby <strong>the</strong> local economy has been previouslyemphasised <strong>in</strong> this text. In addition, <strong>the</strong> areas<strong>in</strong> which TTs must be primarily carried outare those of goods and services that addressdomestic needs through local entrepreneurialactivity. Projects <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se doma<strong>in</strong>s are sociallybeneficial and extraord<strong>in</strong>ary advances mustbe achieved ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong> traditional sectorsthat generate local spillover. Therefore,<strong>the</strong> PPP has to target <strong>the</strong> local demand fortechnologies.On <strong>the</strong> supply side, <strong>the</strong> PPPs must accountfor <strong>the</strong> existence of a certa<strong>in</strong> profile oftechnology holders <strong>in</strong> developed countriesthat can be motivated and proceed efficientlywhen beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g an LDC TT transaction. As aconsequence of a certa<strong>in</strong> stage of verticaldis<strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustries, <strong>the</strong> emergence ofspecialised segments focus<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ventionand development of technologies, while notcompet<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> downstream market, ispositive for TT to LDCs. This is a favourablecontext to f<strong>in</strong>d capable and motivatedsuppliers that are likely to undertake TT <strong>in</strong> anefficient way.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development91.5 Respond<strong>in</strong>g Properly and Effectively to <strong>TRIPS</strong> Article 66.2The role and functions of developed countrygovernments must be exam<strong>in</strong>ed and evaluatedwith regard to <strong>the</strong> different arguments previouslydeveloped. In short, <strong>TRIPS</strong> Article 66.2, which <strong>in</strong>vague terms calls for <strong>the</strong> provision of additional<strong>in</strong>centives to <strong>the</strong> firms and o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>org</strong>anisations ofdeveloped countries to undertake TTs to LDCs,should be made more explicit. Practical meansto achieve this <strong>in</strong>clude:• Rely<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> jo<strong>in</strong>t product and by-productslogics only to ensure a satisfactory flow ofconsolidated technologies towards LDCsdoes not suffice. Above all, TTs as ma<strong>in</strong>operations must be developed. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to<strong>the</strong> new logic, <strong>the</strong> locus of decision-mak<strong>in</strong>gregard<strong>in</strong>g modes of learn<strong>in</strong>g and areas forfocus will likely shift away from foreignbodies to local agents and authorities.• In provid<strong>in</strong>g additional <strong>in</strong>centives to technology-own<strong>in</strong>gfirms, governments are seek<strong>in</strong>geffectiveness. To achieve this, <strong>the</strong>y should:- Provide effective <strong>in</strong>centives by offer<strong>in</strong>gassistance to projects that are sociallybeneficial but not profitable for <strong>the</strong>firms that own and could transfer <strong>the</strong>technology;- Ensure that conditions for efficientTT operations <strong>in</strong>volve <strong>the</strong> choiceof relevant partners on supply anddemand sides, <strong>the</strong> selection of <strong>the</strong>right areas for focus (related toa clearly expressed local demandfor technology) and <strong>the</strong> creationof <strong>org</strong>anisational forms that willfavour <strong>the</strong> consolidation of <strong>the</strong>transfer (absorption, adaptation andsubsequent spillover), as well as <strong>the</strong>related entrepreneurial dynamic;• Make use, as much as possible, of PPPsas a mechanism for ensur<strong>in</strong>g both <strong>the</strong>effectiveness of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>tervention and <strong>the</strong>efficiency of <strong>the</strong> TT operation.


10 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economies2. THE NATURE OF TECHNOLOGY TRANSFERChapter 2 expands on <strong>the</strong> idea of <strong>the</strong> conceptualcomplexity of TT based on <strong>the</strong> dist<strong>in</strong>ctionbetween knowledge and <strong>in</strong>formation. It <strong>the</strong>nexam<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong> different phases that make upthis complexity. It goes on to discuss <strong>the</strong> factthat this complexity becomes even greaterwhen <strong>the</strong> transfer <strong>in</strong>volves entities of verydifferent development levels and demonstrates<strong>the</strong> pivotal nature, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of LDCs, of<strong>the</strong> notion of capabilities. The build<strong>in</strong>g of<strong>the</strong>se capabilities is carried out with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>framework of suitable <strong>org</strong>anisational forms,such as technology platforms or productioncentres. LDCs are also dist<strong>in</strong>ctive with regardto <strong>the</strong> type of <strong>in</strong>novation that is importantto support as an eng<strong>in</strong>e for growth. F<strong>in</strong>ally,chapter 2 tackles <strong>the</strong> question of barriersand <strong>in</strong>centives offered to firms to undertakeTT operations and carry <strong>the</strong>m throughsuccessfully.2.1 Information and KnowledgeDiscussion of TT <strong>in</strong> this paper refers to <strong>the</strong>transmission of technological knowledge. Ofcourse, not only product or process-relatedknowledge, but also <strong>org</strong>anisational knowledgecan be transferred.The channels of transmission may <strong>in</strong>volve tradeand transfers of materials, designs, bluepr<strong>in</strong>ts,scientific papers and patents, formulae, manuals,databases, <strong>in</strong>struments and mach<strong>in</strong>ery, as wellas <strong>the</strong> physical relocation of people possess<strong>in</strong>gspecialised technical abilities and skills. In allcases, <strong>the</strong> transferr<strong>in</strong>g of knowledge is different,more complex and costlier than <strong>the</strong> dissem<strong>in</strong>ationof <strong>in</strong>formation concern<strong>in</strong>g a technology.Dissem<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation is simpler andless costly than <strong>the</strong> activity of transferr<strong>in</strong>gtechnological capabilities to <strong>in</strong>dividuals,<strong>org</strong>anisations and, on a wider scale, social aggregationsthat were previously lack<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m.While a TT can be considered a success if<strong>the</strong> technology <strong>in</strong> question has been put <strong>in</strong>tooperation and resulted <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>creased productivity<strong>in</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong> economic activity, it is only <strong>the</strong>creation of technological capabilities <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>host country that will ensure <strong>the</strong> long-stand<strong>in</strong>gefficient use of that technology <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> countryconsidered.This section elucidates <strong>the</strong> content and implicationsof <strong>the</strong> dist<strong>in</strong>ction between knowledgeand <strong>in</strong>formation. Box 1 below systematicallyexpla<strong>in</strong>s all <strong>the</strong> properties and characteristicsof knowledge that make its transfer andmanagement difficult.As conceived here, knowledge entails someth<strong>in</strong>gmore than <strong>in</strong>formation (Foray, 2004).Knowledge, <strong>in</strong> whatever field, empowers itspossessors with <strong>the</strong> capacity for <strong>in</strong>tellectualor physical action. The mean<strong>in</strong>g of knowledgehere is fundamentally as a matter of cognitivecapability. Information, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand,assumes <strong>the</strong> form of structured and formatteddata that rema<strong>in</strong>s passive and <strong>in</strong>ert until used bythose with <strong>the</strong> necessary knowledge to <strong>in</strong>terpretand process <strong>the</strong>m.The full mean<strong>in</strong>g of this dist<strong>in</strong>ction becomesclear when <strong>the</strong> conditions govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>reproduction of knowledge and <strong>in</strong>formationare exam<strong>in</strong>ed. While <strong>the</strong> cost of replicat<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>formation amounts for no more than <strong>the</strong> cost ofmak<strong>in</strong>g copies (next to noth<strong>in</strong>g thanks to moderntechnology), reproduc<strong>in</strong>g knowledge is a far moreexpensive process s<strong>in</strong>ce cognitive capabilitiesare not easy to articulate explicitly or transferto o<strong>the</strong>rs: “we can know more than we cantell” (Polanyi, 1966). Knowledge reproductionhas <strong>the</strong>refore long h<strong>in</strong>ged on <strong>the</strong> “masterapprentice”system (where a young person’scapacity is moulded by watch<strong>in</strong>g, listen<strong>in</strong>g andimitat<strong>in</strong>g) or on <strong>in</strong>terpersonal transactions amongmembers of <strong>the</strong> same profession or communityof practice. These means of reproduc<strong>in</strong>gknowledge may rema<strong>in</strong> at <strong>the</strong> heart of manyprofessions and traditions, but <strong>the</strong>y can easily


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development11fail to operate when social ties unravel, contactis lost between older and younger generations,and professional communities lose <strong>the</strong>ir capacityto act <strong>in</strong> stabilis<strong>in</strong>g, preserv<strong>in</strong>g and transmitt<strong>in</strong>gknowledge. In such cases, reproduction gr<strong>in</strong>dsto a halt and <strong>the</strong> knowledge <strong>in</strong> question is <strong>in</strong>imm<strong>in</strong>ent danger of be<strong>in</strong>g lost and f<strong>org</strong>otten.Therefore, <strong>the</strong> reproduction of knowledge and<strong>the</strong> reproduction of <strong>in</strong>formation are clearlydifferent phenomena. While one occurs throughlearn<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r occurs simply throughduplication. Mobilisation of a cognitive resourceis always necessary for <strong>the</strong> reproduction ofknowledge, while <strong>in</strong>formation can be reproducedby a photocopy mach<strong>in</strong>e.A fur<strong>the</strong>r complication is <strong>the</strong> fact that knowledgecan be codified: that is, articulated and clarified<strong>in</strong> such a way that it can be expressed <strong>in</strong> aparticular language and recorded via a particularmedium. Codification <strong>in</strong>volves <strong>the</strong> exteriorisationof memory. It h<strong>in</strong>ges on a range of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>glycomplex actions such as us<strong>in</strong>g language to writea cook<strong>in</strong>g recipe, apply<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustrial designtechniques to draft a scale draw<strong>in</strong>g of a pieceof mach<strong>in</strong>ery, creat<strong>in</strong>g an expert system from<strong>the</strong> formalised rules of <strong>in</strong>ference underly<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>sequence of stages geared to problem solv<strong>in</strong>g, andso on. As such, knowledge is detached from <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>dividual, and <strong>the</strong> memory and communicationcapacity created are made <strong>in</strong>dependent ofhuman be<strong>in</strong>gs (as long as <strong>the</strong> medium upon which<strong>the</strong> knowledge is stored is safeguarded and <strong>the</strong>language <strong>in</strong> which it is expressed remembered).Learn<strong>in</strong>g programmes are <strong>the</strong>n produced thatpartially replace <strong>the</strong> person who possesses andteaches knowledge.When knowledge is differentiated from <strong>in</strong>formation,economic problems relat<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> twocan be dist<strong>in</strong>guished. Where knowledge isconcerned, <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> economic problem is itsreproduction and transfer (problem of learn<strong>in</strong>g),while <strong>the</strong> reproduction of <strong>in</strong>formation poses noreal problem (<strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al cost of reproductionis close to zero). The economic problem of<strong>in</strong>formation concerns essentially its protectionand disclosure: that is, a problem of publicgoods. However, <strong>the</strong> codification of knowledgecreates an ambiguous good. This good hascerta<strong>in</strong> properties of <strong>in</strong>formation (public good)but its reproduction, as knowledge requires <strong>the</strong>mobilisation of cognitive resources.Box 1. Knowledge as a CommodityKnowledge is Sticky and TacitThere is codified technological knowledge that is quite easy to transfer s<strong>in</strong>ce it ma<strong>in</strong>ly<strong>in</strong>volves <strong>the</strong> “costless travel” of a paper, software, or database. But new knowledge andexpertise have a broad tacit dimension, mean<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong>y are nei<strong>the</strong>r articulated norcodified. Tacit knowledge resides <strong>in</strong> people, <strong>in</strong>stitutions, or rout<strong>in</strong>es. Tacitness makesknowledge difficult to transport, memorise, recomb<strong>in</strong>e and learn – all operations ofhigh importance <strong>in</strong> TT activities. For <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>the</strong> knowledge <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> effectiveproduction of advanced <strong>in</strong>formation technology products entails far more than <strong>the</strong>transfer of a set of bluepr<strong>in</strong>ts. Given tacitness, knowledge is, <strong>the</strong>refore, costly to transferfrom one site to ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong> a useable form. As von Hippel (1994) puts it, knowledge issticky. Knowledge stick<strong>in</strong>ess refers to <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cremental expenditure required to transfera unit of knowledge to a specified locus <strong>in</strong> a form usable by a given knowledge seeker.When this cost is high, stick<strong>in</strong>ess is high. Stick<strong>in</strong>ess raises a number of issues <strong>in</strong> terms of<strong>the</strong> <strong>org</strong>anisation of knowledge production, product design and system <strong>in</strong>tegration.Industrial and technological operations draw crucially upon sets of human skills andtechniques that have been acquired experientially and are transferred between peopleby demonstration, <strong>in</strong>formal personal <strong>in</strong>struction, advice and consultations, ra<strong>the</strong>r thanbe<strong>in</strong>g reduced to explicit and codified methods and procedures. Even <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustries wheremature technologies are transferred, tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g costs can be substantial and greater thanadaptive R&D costs.


12 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesMany production processes that are implemented by people try<strong>in</strong>g to follow <strong>the</strong> codified<strong>in</strong>structions without hav<strong>in</strong>g access to <strong>the</strong> complementary tacit understand<strong>in</strong>g of expertsfail to deliver outputs of <strong>the</strong> expected quality immediately, and for a long time producebelow <strong>the</strong> rates anticipated.With regard to TTs, <strong>the</strong> tacitness and stick<strong>in</strong>ess of knowledge create transactionaldifficulties. The difficulties created by <strong>the</strong> complementary role of tacit knowledge <strong>in</strong>successfully transferr<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>completely codified technological knowledge from advancedto develop<strong>in</strong>g countries suggests that <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g firms from <strong>the</strong> former countries viacooperative ventures, technology support and tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g contracts will be <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terestsof firms <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> latter countries.Knowledge is Partially LocalisedTechnological knowledge is often not of general value for <strong>the</strong> economy because it hasbeen produced <strong>in</strong> a local context for particular purposes. A large body of literatureargues that <strong>the</strong> production of knowledge is at least partially localised: learn<strong>in</strong>g thatimproves one technology may have little or no effect on o<strong>the</strong>r technologies. However<strong>the</strong> degree of standardisation and maturation of technology and knowledge can mitigate<strong>the</strong>se difficulties.The o<strong>the</strong>r facet of this property is that local environments are subject to strong variations:even str<strong>in</strong>gent requirements for equipment duplication cannot elim<strong>in</strong>ate all significantdifferences between local environments (Appleyard et al., 1996). As expla<strong>in</strong>ed by Ho(1997), because a technology is developed for specific conditions, transferr<strong>in</strong>g it toan environment different from that for which it is designed often requires adaptationbefore it can be successfully absorbed. In fact, a technology is rarely <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong>to anew environment without some adaptations.Knowledge is Weakly PersistentEvidence <strong>in</strong> psychological literature shows that people f<strong>org</strong>et: if <strong>the</strong> practice of a task is<strong>in</strong>terrupted, f<strong>org</strong>ett<strong>in</strong>g occurs. Hirsch (1952) found that when performance was resumedafter <strong>in</strong>terruption it was at a lower level than that achieved prior to <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terruption.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, knowledge can be depreciated (through deterioration and obsolescence).Communities that are <strong>in</strong> possession of it can fall apart, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> dis<strong>in</strong>tegration of<strong>the</strong>ir collective knowledge.Knowledge is often a Jo<strong>in</strong>t productKnowledge is produced <strong>in</strong> a context of activities <strong>in</strong> which o<strong>the</strong>r motivations (<strong>the</strong>manufactur<strong>in</strong>g of a good or provision of a service) are predom<strong>in</strong>ant. People learn bydo<strong>in</strong>g or by us<strong>in</strong>g. There is learn<strong>in</strong>g-by-do<strong>in</strong>g because knowledge is not absolute but mustbe def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> relation to a specific physical context. Such a characteristic gives manyactivities important potential value <strong>in</strong> terms of knowledge production and <strong>in</strong>novation:those activities related, for <strong>in</strong>stance, to <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>troduction of a novel type of equipment,<strong>org</strong>anisation, or method.Knowledge is Progressive and CumulativeIn <strong>the</strong> field of science and technology, knowledge is more often than not cumulativeand progressive: technological improvement is <strong>the</strong>refore a central issue and a criticalchallenge for workers and eng<strong>in</strong>eers who need to recognise and exploit <strong>the</strong> latestimprovement. An <strong>org</strong>anisation must thus be far more technically competent to advancewith <strong>the</strong> times (to advance with <strong>the</strong> state of <strong>the</strong> art) than to stand still.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development132.2 Consolidation of <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>2.2.1 Evidence on CostsTeece’s empirical works about TTs bymult<strong>in</strong>ational companies (1977) showed that<strong>the</strong> transmission and absorption of <strong>the</strong> knowhowrequired to actually put <strong>the</strong> technology<strong>in</strong>to operation <strong>in</strong>volved substantial costs.These averaged roughly 20 per cent of <strong>the</strong> totalproject costs and were supplementary to <strong>the</strong>cost of transmitt<strong>in</strong>g knowledge <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> form ofcapital goods, bluepr<strong>in</strong>ts, specifications andspecial materials. Also <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> costwere pre-eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g technological exchanges,eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g costs associated with transferr<strong>in</strong>gprocess or product design, and <strong>the</strong> associatedprocess – or product –eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g, as well asR&D necessary for tailor<strong>in</strong>g technology to suitlocal conditions. They also <strong>in</strong>cluded pre-start-uptra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g costs and outlays made dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>itial‘shakedown’ and ‘debugg<strong>in</strong>g’ phases of learn<strong>in</strong>gthat was required for <strong>the</strong> plant to achieve itsdesigned performance specifications.Cost variations are clearly related to <strong>the</strong>fundamental objective of <strong>the</strong> TT, whe<strong>the</strong>r toacquire <strong>the</strong> capacity to produce a productaccord<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> design and specificationsof o<strong>the</strong>rs (material transfer), to acquire <strong>the</strong>capacity to produce a product and make m<strong>in</strong>ordesign and technical changes (design transfer),or, to lessen dependence on foreign technology(i.e. to acquire <strong>the</strong> capacity to develop one’sown technology).Evidence regard<strong>in</strong>g costs is a relatively good<strong>in</strong>dication of <strong>the</strong> fact that a TT <strong>in</strong>volves morethan <strong>the</strong> mere acquisition of <strong>in</strong>formation abouttechnology. Not only must <strong>the</strong> knowledge besuccessfully transferred for <strong>the</strong> technologyto be put <strong>in</strong>to operation, but persistence andmemory have to be ensured and new knowledgegenerated must adapt <strong>the</strong> technology to <strong>the</strong>new environment and application. This newknowledge has, <strong>in</strong>-turn, to be managed,memorised, adop-ted and shared. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>the</strong>assimilation of subsequent knowledge improvementsis a critical requirement.Moreover, <strong>the</strong> skills necessary for putt<strong>in</strong>ga technology <strong>in</strong>to operation appear to be<strong>org</strong>anisational, ra<strong>the</strong>r than exclusively <strong>in</strong>dividual.Recurrent difficulties <strong>in</strong> absorb<strong>in</strong>g newtechnologies dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> 1960s and 1970s ledpolicymakers to def<strong>in</strong>e technology more broadlyfor it to <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>org</strong>anisational and managementskills and know-how, ra<strong>the</strong>r than just eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> a narrow sense. This enabled <strong>the</strong> developmentof a greater appreciation of <strong>the</strong> importance ofacquir<strong>in</strong>g “software” (disembodied <strong>in</strong>formation<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> form of codified <strong>in</strong>structions and directionsfor use) and above all “wetware” (what is <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>memories of <strong>in</strong>dividuals), as well as technologyembodied <strong>in</strong> physical capital (Ho, 1997). Onefirm hir<strong>in</strong>g ano<strong>the</strong>r firm’s most skilled eng<strong>in</strong>eersmay be necessary but not sufficient to “reverseeng<strong>in</strong>eer” and successfully transfer <strong>the</strong> newtechnology (Appleyard et al., 1996).The learn<strong>in</strong>g capacity of <strong>the</strong> recipient is <strong>the</strong>reforevital: countries that spend relatively largeamounts on R&D <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> relevant <strong>in</strong>dustry tendto be quick to beg<strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>g a new producteven if <strong>the</strong>y are not its <strong>in</strong>ventor. Similarly, firmsthat spend relatively large amounts on R&D tendto quickly adopt new technology developed byo<strong>the</strong>rs (Mansfield, 1982).2.2.2 ConsolidationConceptually, <strong>the</strong> consolidation of TT <strong>in</strong>volvesdifferent phases and steps: absorption andlearn<strong>in</strong>g, adaptation to <strong>the</strong> local environmentand needs (which is likely to <strong>in</strong>clude true<strong>in</strong>novative work), assimilation of subsequentimprovements and, f<strong>in</strong>ally, generalisation.The absorption phase basically correspondsto <strong>in</strong>itial activities dedicated to <strong>the</strong>learn<strong>in</strong>g and application of <strong>the</strong> importedtechnological knowledge, plus <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>tenanceof equipment and its long-termperformance.


14 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesThe phase of adaptation to local conditions maycomprise development and <strong>in</strong>novation tasks,not entail<strong>in</strong>g major discont<strong>in</strong>uity, but allow<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> imported technology to be adjusted to localspecificities, on both <strong>the</strong> supply and demand sides.The assimilation of subsequent improvementsphase signifies that <strong>the</strong> improvements of <strong>the</strong>technological knowledge do not of coursecome to an end once <strong>the</strong> transfer has beenmade. Sometimes, <strong>the</strong>se improvements are apure extrapolation of exist<strong>in</strong>g phenomena and<strong>the</strong>refore <strong>the</strong>ir mastery only requires an extensionbeyond <strong>the</strong> present boundaries; at o<strong>the</strong>r times,<strong>the</strong> improvements <strong>in</strong>volve <strong>the</strong> open<strong>in</strong>g up of newareas of knowledge, <strong>in</strong> which case <strong>the</strong>ir masteryconfronts <strong>the</strong> operat<strong>in</strong>g personnel with newphenomena.F<strong>in</strong>ally <strong>the</strong> generalisation phase correspondsto <strong>the</strong> dynamics of adoption of <strong>the</strong> transferredtechnology by all <strong>the</strong> potential adopters. Thisgeneralisation also <strong>in</strong>cludes <strong>the</strong> dissem<strong>in</strong>ation ofimported technological knowledge.2.3. TT <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Context of LDCs: Capabilities, Organisational Design and Modelsof Innovation<strong>Technology</strong> transfers between developedeconomies and LDCs <strong>in</strong>volve very specific issuesand must be treated as an entirely differenttopic, as opposed to TTs occurr<strong>in</strong>g betweentwo firms with <strong>the</strong> same level of technologicalcapacities and management capabilities, forexample.TT between developed economies and LDCs<strong>in</strong>volves <strong>the</strong> transfer, implementation andabsorption of a technology from a maturetechnological structure to an entirely disarticulatedproduction and knowledge system.Each consolidation phase – absorption oftechnology, adaptation to local conditions,assimilation of subsequent improvements, andgeneralisation – causes significant difficulties.As opposed to a TT <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g two entities of <strong>the</strong>2.3.1 Capabilitiessame level of development, greater attentionmust generally be paid to:• Learn<strong>in</strong>g and tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g services;• What is imported <strong>in</strong> terms of equipment(some sources of failure are importation of<strong>the</strong> wrong equipment, <strong>in</strong>complete sets ofequipment, or <strong>in</strong>appropriate equipment);• The sufficient availability of high qualitylocal raw material and components (amajor source of failure is <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>adequatesupply of local raw material andcomponents (see Ho, 1997));• The local demand structure (productsunsuited to <strong>the</strong> local market constituteano<strong>the</strong>r source of failure).The term “capabilities” here draws on Enos(1996) to <strong>in</strong>troduce an issue relevant for <strong>the</strong>least technologically advanced firms. The mosttechnologically advanced firms can profitablyabsorb new knowledge and subsequent improvements,and undertake development to adapt <strong>the</strong>technology to specific conditions. They employ<strong>the</strong> skilled persons needed to appreciate andassimilate advanced technologies, and can drawupon <strong>the</strong>ir previous experience <strong>in</strong> carry<strong>in</strong>g outeach successive task. <strong>Technology</strong> transfer is <strong>in</strong>fact a decreas<strong>in</strong>g cost activity. The more extensive<strong>the</strong> experience previously acquired by <strong>the</strong>transferr<strong>in</strong>g <strong>org</strong>anisation <strong>in</strong> supply<strong>in</strong>g subsidiarieswith <strong>the</strong> technology <strong>in</strong> question, <strong>the</strong> narrower<strong>the</strong> gap between <strong>the</strong> technical capabilities of <strong>the</strong>two participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>org</strong>anisations, and <strong>the</strong> lower<strong>the</strong> transfer costs <strong>in</strong> relation to total project size(Mansfield, 1995).Less advanced firms lack <strong>the</strong>se prerequisites fortechnological progress: even if <strong>the</strong>y draw uponoutside suppliers for <strong>the</strong> tasks of plann<strong>in</strong>g, design,eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g, construction and <strong>in</strong>itial operation,<strong>the</strong>y are likely to f<strong>in</strong>d <strong>the</strong>mselves <strong>in</strong>capable ofoperat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> plant <strong>in</strong> a way that exploits its fullpotential, let alone secur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> mundane dayto-dayimprovements that so markedly <strong>in</strong>crease


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development15its performance. It may take all <strong>the</strong> technicaland managerial resources of <strong>the</strong> less advancedfirms to master <strong>the</strong> transferred technologyand implement <strong>the</strong> necessary adaptations anddevelopments. Master<strong>in</strong>g improvements as <strong>the</strong>ycome along may prove too great a challenge.Master<strong>in</strong>g a given state of <strong>the</strong> art is not enough;what is critical is to master a progressive state of<strong>the</strong> art (Enos, 1996). In <strong>the</strong> knowledge economy,<strong>the</strong>se tasks are never-end<strong>in</strong>g. No sooner haveworkers mastered one state of <strong>the</strong> art that <strong>the</strong>ymust beg<strong>in</strong> to shift <strong>the</strong>ir attention to its successor.Improvement can occur so rapidly that workerscan never relax th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>y have absorbed <strong>the</strong>current set of knowledge, as <strong>the</strong> next phase ofimprovements is already upon <strong>the</strong>m.Build<strong>in</strong>g capabilities to <strong>in</strong>crease a TT’s chancesof success is thus a crucial matter. It po<strong>in</strong>tstowards economic models of developmentthat emphasise <strong>the</strong> accumulation of skills andlearn<strong>in</strong>g capacities, ra<strong>the</strong>r than fixed assetsor capital, <strong>in</strong> facilitat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> TT process. This,<strong>in</strong> turn, calls for certa<strong>in</strong> proper <strong>org</strong>anisationalstructures.2.3.2 Organisational designOrganisational structures are critical for <strong>the</strong>successful management of <strong>the</strong> whole TT process.What is at stake here is an idea that goes back toA. Marshall’s concept of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternal and external<strong>org</strong>anisation of firms. The <strong>in</strong>ternal <strong>org</strong>anisationof <strong>the</strong> receiv<strong>in</strong>g entity is central to <strong>the</strong> processof technology absorption and its adaptation tolocal conditions, as well as <strong>the</strong> assimilation ofsubsequent improvements. External <strong>org</strong>anisationis critical to <strong>the</strong> process of broader dissem<strong>in</strong>ationand spillover from one particular entry po<strong>in</strong>t of<strong>the</strong> technology <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> country.These two <strong>org</strong>anisational dimensions are likelyto be “weak” <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of LDCs. It is <strong>the</strong>reforecritical to establish <strong>org</strong>anisational structuresthat are dedicated to improve both <strong>in</strong>ternal andexternal dimensions <strong>in</strong> order to maximise <strong>the</strong>probability of TT success.The terms “technology platform” or “productioncentre” are used to designate forms of <strong>org</strong>anisationexplicitly aimed at facilitat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> learn<strong>in</strong>gof <strong>the</strong> technology, its adaptation to localconditions, <strong>the</strong> assimilation of subsequentimprovements and its generalisation. Theseessentially <strong>in</strong>volve technology developmentcentres devoted to a specific doma<strong>in</strong> and partlyf<strong>in</strong>anced by public development assistance.These centres provide a certa<strong>in</strong> number oftechnological services to assure <strong>the</strong> developmentof appropriate <strong>in</strong>novations. They p<strong>in</strong>po<strong>in</strong>t andstructure demand for technology from localentrepreneurs. They also ensure <strong>the</strong> updat<strong>in</strong>gof technological knowledge and its diffusion.Crucially, <strong>the</strong>y facilitate access to <strong>the</strong> f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>gof <strong>in</strong>novation by local banks, ei<strong>the</strong>r by simplysupport<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> project <strong>in</strong> question, or creat<strong>in</strong>gcredit l<strong>in</strong>es from developed countries. Box 2describes this type of project us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> exampleof <strong>the</strong> Cleaner Production Centers set up aspart of collaboration between Switzerland’sState Secretariat for Economic Affairs (SECO),<strong>the</strong> United Nations Industrial DevelopmentOrganisation (UNIDO) and several develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries.<strong>Technology</strong> platforms constitute an attractive<strong>org</strong>anisational <strong>in</strong>novation when <strong>the</strong> TT<strong>in</strong>volves countries with different levels ofdevelopment. They represent a method ofcoord<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g and adapt<strong>in</strong>g resources whoseassembly is, by def<strong>in</strong>ition, problematic.They provide a better understand<strong>in</strong>g oflocal technology demands. F<strong>in</strong>ally – andperhaps most importantly – <strong>the</strong>y “anchor”<strong>the</strong> technological development <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> localeconomy, endeavour<strong>in</strong>g to attach it to an<strong>in</strong>dustrial dynamic.A TT l<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g entities with very different developmentlevels calls for sophisticated <strong>org</strong>anisationalforms if <strong>the</strong> success of <strong>the</strong> differentconsolidation phases is to be guaranteed.However, <strong>the</strong>se <strong>org</strong>anisational forms are<strong>the</strong>mselves heavily dependent on <strong>the</strong> chosentransaction modes, as discussed fur<strong>the</strong>r below.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development172.3.3.1 The centrality of local <strong>in</strong>novation and local spilloverInnovation should be widely distributed over<strong>the</strong> whole spectrum of economic activitiesacross sectors (not just high tech) and typesof <strong>in</strong>novations (not just formal R&D). In LDCs,this means <strong>in</strong>cremental, cumulative, andmostly <strong>in</strong>formal (without R&D) <strong>in</strong>novations,developed ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong> “traditional” sectors or <strong>in</strong>services not qualify<strong>in</strong>g as “high tech.” Althoughmostly deal<strong>in</strong>g with low-tech activities, <strong>the</strong>se<strong>in</strong>novations are generat<strong>in</strong>g local spillover andwill ultimately impact <strong>the</strong> productivity of awide range of sectors <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> local economy.If we regard <strong>in</strong>formation and communicationtechnologies (ICTs) as <strong>the</strong> major generalpurpose technology of our time, ever expand<strong>in</strong>gsegments of LDC economies should adopt and“<strong>in</strong>vent” new applications for ICTs <strong>in</strong> waysthat <strong>in</strong>crease productivity. General PurposeTechnologies (GPT) foster economy-widegrowth not simply or pr<strong>in</strong>cipally by <strong>in</strong>novation<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> GPT itself, but ra<strong>the</strong>r when a wide andexpand<strong>in</strong>g range of o<strong>the</strong>r sectors adopt <strong>the</strong>advanc<strong>in</strong>g technology, generat<strong>in</strong>g new usefulapplications of <strong>the</strong> GPT. Therefore, <strong>the</strong> keyissue for “secondary countries” (countriesthat are not at <strong>the</strong> frontier of <strong>the</strong> GPT) is howto allocate R&D and o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>novative <strong>in</strong>putsso as to level <strong>the</strong> growth potential of <strong>the</strong>prevalent GPT. The ma<strong>in</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t is that it is notICTs alone that cause growth, but ra<strong>the</strong>r thatadopt<strong>in</strong>g sectors ought to establish <strong>in</strong>novationcomplementarities for economy-wide growthto take place. These types of <strong>in</strong>novationcomplementarities (adoption, local <strong>in</strong>novations<strong>in</strong> traditional sectors) may be less overtly<strong>in</strong>novative and <strong>the</strong>refore not be deemed asworthy of support or encouragement. Yet,ultimately, <strong>the</strong>y constitute <strong>the</strong> key to economicgrowth.Any <strong>in</strong>novation policy <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of LDCsshould, <strong>the</strong>refore, pay attention to <strong>the</strong>seissues. It should not aim just at <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gtotal R&D, but do so <strong>in</strong> a way that <strong>in</strong>centiviseslocal <strong>in</strong>novation and spillover ra<strong>the</strong>r thanglobal R&D and external leakages. Such apolicy should develop absorptive capacity andultimately impact <strong>the</strong> productivity of a widerange of sectors <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> local economy.This is <strong>the</strong> “model” of <strong>in</strong>novation that TThas to foster <strong>in</strong> an LDC context. From thisperspective, government and donors shouldpay more attention to local demand fortechnology. Much of <strong>the</strong> discussion <strong>in</strong> TTliterature has focused on <strong>the</strong> supply side – <strong>the</strong>will<strong>in</strong>gness of technology holders to transfertechnology (Arora, 2007). Very little attentionhas been paid to provid<strong>in</strong>g better knowledgeof <strong>the</strong> structure of <strong>the</strong> demand for technology<strong>in</strong> a given country, region, or <strong>in</strong>dustry.2.3.3.2 Discover<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> next areas for focusAccord<strong>in</strong>g to Hausman and Rodrick (2002), <strong>the</strong>reis a key role for entrepreneurs <strong>in</strong> LDCs: to learnwhat <strong>the</strong> country is good at produc<strong>in</strong>g. For anLDC, <strong>the</strong>re is great social value <strong>in</strong> discover<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>relevant specialisation s<strong>in</strong>ce this knowledge canorient <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments of o<strong>the</strong>r entrepreneurs.It is also a misperception of LDCs’ realities toassume that <strong>the</strong> production functions of allextant goods are common knowledge.But <strong>the</strong> entrepreneur who makes <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>itial“discovery” can capture only a small part of<strong>the</strong> social value generated by this knowledge;o<strong>the</strong>r entrepreneurs can quickly emulate suchdiscovery. Consequently, entrepreneurship ofthis type – generat<strong>in</strong>g learn<strong>in</strong>g on what can beproduced – will be undersupplied.If learn<strong>in</strong>g what a country is good at produc<strong>in</strong>grequires an <strong>in</strong>vestment and <strong>the</strong> return on this<strong>in</strong>vestment cannot be fully appropriated, this isa problem that is unlikely to be solved with legalprotection. Indeed, entrepreneurs <strong>in</strong> LDCs aretry<strong>in</strong>g out technologies that already exist abroad.The discovery may be that an exist<strong>in</strong>g good canbe produced profitably <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> country. Suchdiscovery does not normally get legal protectionno matter how high <strong>the</strong> social return. There is<strong>the</strong>refore a role for government policy, probablynot fulfilled by <strong>the</strong> IP protection system.


18 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economies2.4 The Choice of <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> Areas <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Case of LDCsIn a note-worthy case study of science andtechnology policy <strong>in</strong> four sub-Saharan countries(Ghana, Kenya, Tanzania and Uganda), Enos(1998) clearly demonstrates that <strong>the</strong> areas ofscience and technology most vigorously pursued<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se countries are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly determ<strong>in</strong>ed byforeigners. Tanzania’s Agricultural Master Plan,for example, assigns <strong>the</strong> first R&D priorities tocoffee, tea, rice, animal health, soil and watermanagement, and ‘farm system’ research,<strong>in</strong> that order. Of course, sett<strong>in</strong>g priorities,plann<strong>in</strong>g, and allocat<strong>in</strong>g resources to undertakeresearch accord<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong>se priorities are highlydesirable policy actions. However, <strong>the</strong> questionis: on what bases are <strong>the</strong> priorities set? Who does<strong>the</strong> sett<strong>in</strong>g? Is <strong>the</strong>re any impact?2.4.1 Enos’ ma<strong>in</strong> argument: <strong>the</strong> process used to determ<strong>in</strong>e priorities is dubiousAs described <strong>in</strong> Box 3, Enos has six strongarguments to describe <strong>the</strong> vicious circle forthose economies <strong>in</strong> which <strong>the</strong> decision locus hasshifted to foreigners and where <strong>the</strong> re-focus ison scientific and technological progress <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>area of export-oriented commodities fac<strong>in</strong>gdeteriorat<strong>in</strong>g terms of trade <strong>in</strong>stead of areas ofdomestic expansion.Box 3. Def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Areas of Focus: Six Arguments1. Enos argues that <strong>the</strong>re is a shift <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> locus of decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g concern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> futuredirection of economies from local authorities to foreign assistance bodies. This is likelyto cont<strong>in</strong>ue for a long time s<strong>in</strong>ce local resources devoted to <strong>the</strong> pursuit of scienceand technology are scarce and it may well be decades before <strong>the</strong> countries will havesufficient resources to f<strong>in</strong>ance scientific education and R&D without foreign support.Let us go back to Tanzania’s selection of target areas <strong>in</strong> science and technology tounderstand what is go<strong>in</strong>g on. Obviously <strong>the</strong> criterion used to select R&D <strong>in</strong> coffee, cotton,and tea <strong>in</strong> that order is based on <strong>the</strong> country’s export specialisations that provide <strong>the</strong>biggest export earn<strong>in</strong>gs for f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g national development. The argument is as follows:<strong>the</strong> countries are short of foreign earn<strong>in</strong>gs with which <strong>the</strong>y f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>the</strong>ir development.An <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> capability of <strong>the</strong>se countries to provide <strong>the</strong> goods and services desiredabroad will help grow <strong>the</strong>ir foreign earn<strong>in</strong>gs. And, <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> foreign markets for <strong>the</strong>segoods and services have always been, and will rema<strong>in</strong>, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> developed countries. Theargument is thus that <strong>the</strong>se economies will best serve <strong>the</strong>ir own members by conform<strong>in</strong>gto <strong>the</strong> exist<strong>in</strong>g pattern of world trade.2. Decisions made by foreigners regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> direction taken by science and technologyare primarily based on <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple of comparative advantage. A country should <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong> activities that can potentially be carried out at a relatively lower cost than <strong>in</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r countries. So some activities, such as production of textiles and process<strong>in</strong>g oftropical foodstuffs, are excluded from <strong>the</strong> menu of activities appropriate for develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries (<strong>the</strong>y are reserved for producers <strong>in</strong> developed countries). As a result, <strong>the</strong>menu of activities available is very restricted. It essentially <strong>in</strong>cludes those commoditiesthat are consumed but not produced <strong>in</strong> developed countries: primary commodities suchas beverages (cocoa, coffee, tea) and, to a lesser extent, fibres (cotton and wood).Scientific research is undertaken to <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>the</strong> production and lower <strong>the</strong> costs ofproduc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>se commodities. Education is directed towards tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g people who willorient <strong>the</strong>ir careers accord<strong>in</strong>gly.3. The choice of science and technology areas to be pursued is primarily based upon<strong>the</strong> effects of such choices on developed countries. This means that among <strong>the</strong> variousareas where Tanzania has a comparative advantage, <strong>the</strong> commodities accorded highestpriorities are those that are not produced by <strong>the</strong> countries sponsor<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> master plan,which <strong>in</strong>cludes <strong>the</strong> EU, Germany, <strong>the</strong> Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands, and <strong>the</strong> UK. Not only do developed


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development19countries support R&D <strong>in</strong> those commodities that <strong>the</strong>y import but <strong>the</strong>y also tend toensure that <strong>the</strong>se are <strong>the</strong> very commodities that receive <strong>the</strong> most R&D.Tanzania certa<strong>in</strong>ly has a comparative advantage <strong>in</strong> coffee or tea. As such, this is ageneral argument to allocate resources for technological development to <strong>the</strong>se areas.However, Tanzania may also have a comparative advantage <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> production of maize,roots and tubers, oil seeds, and etc., which are considered as a medium priority <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>master plan. R&D <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se areas will thus receive far less attention.Why is this happen<strong>in</strong>g? From <strong>the</strong> donor po<strong>in</strong>t of view, <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>the</strong> need not to offendpowerful groups of producers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> developed countries, <strong>the</strong> universal aim of exportpromotion, and <strong>the</strong> reliance of <strong>the</strong> country considered on competitive advantagecriteria.4. The implication of arguments one, two, and three above on <strong>the</strong> shift <strong>in</strong> decisionmak<strong>in</strong>gs,comparative advantage rationale, and <strong>the</strong> dom<strong>in</strong>ance of effects on developedcountries, is <strong>the</strong> change <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> aim of economic development; <strong>the</strong> shift is from domesticexpansion to export promotion. Export promotion <strong>in</strong>volves focus<strong>in</strong>g on world markets,discover<strong>in</strong>g those products most <strong>in</strong> demand, and mobilis<strong>in</strong>g domestic resources for thatpurpose. Between domestic expansion and export promotion, <strong>the</strong>re is an obvious clash,at least <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> short-term.5. Focus<strong>in</strong>g on technological progress <strong>in</strong> a given area of export-oriented commodity is acorrect decision for a s<strong>in</strong>gle country (<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> absence of o<strong>the</strong>r countries adopt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> samedecision). But it is likely to be a wrong decision when many countries adopt it. The cha<strong>in</strong>of events is well known for commodities for which demand is price <strong>in</strong>elastic: <strong>the</strong> totalvalue of <strong>the</strong> marketed commodity falls. Second, <strong>the</strong> country has reallocated resourcesto an activity that yields fewer returns as time passes. The cost of this reallocation maybe high and is sunk. Third, <strong>the</strong> country is left with a monoculture.6. It is unfortunate that <strong>the</strong>se countries are allocat<strong>in</strong>g most of <strong>the</strong>ir resources for scienceand technology to areas fac<strong>in</strong>g deteriorat<strong>in</strong>g terms of trade. Devot<strong>in</strong>g scarce R&D to<strong>the</strong>ir improvement will merely accelerate this deterioration. R&D and its concomitantactivities should <strong>the</strong>refore be directed elsewhere.The severe deterioration of terms of trade is thus an emerg<strong>in</strong>g property of demand<strong>in</strong>elasticity and <strong>the</strong> successful transfer of technologies carried out to improve similaractivities <strong>in</strong> too many LDCs.2.4.2 The question <strong>the</strong>n is “where else?”In pr<strong>in</strong>ciple, <strong>the</strong> answer is quite simple and wasprovided <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> preced<strong>in</strong>g section (2.3.3.1).That is, greater advances should be sought <strong>in</strong>those activities that provide employment for arapidly expand<strong>in</strong>g population and generate <strong>the</strong>production of goods and services for domesticconsumption. Thus <strong>the</strong> aims of advanc<strong>in</strong>g scienceand technology are: modest ga<strong>in</strong>s for exportcommodities characterised by deteriorat<strong>in</strong>gterms of trade, and immodest ga<strong>in</strong>s for nontradedgoods and activities like tourism, whichuse relatively abundant resources to earn foreignexchange. This last area could be referred toas “stable-terms-of-trade goods” <strong>in</strong> order todist<strong>in</strong>guish it from exportable commodities likecoffee whose terms of trade will cont<strong>in</strong>ue todeteriorate <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> future.To summarise, <strong>the</strong> aims of science and technologypolicy <strong>in</strong> LDCs are to make reasonable advances<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> area of exportable commodities andextraord<strong>in</strong>ary advances <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> areas of goodsfor domestic consumption and stable-terms-oftradegoods.


20 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesTable 2. Mapp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Areas for TT focusProduct typeExamplesCurrentproductionpotentialR&DcontributionDemandelasticitySupplyelasticityTerms oftrade (trend)TraditionalexportablecommodityCoffee Excellent Moderate Low High Deteriorat<strong>in</strong>gTraditionallocallyconsumedprimarycommodityCottonExcellentModerate tosubstantialwithsufficientR&DMedium High StableLocallyprocessedperishablegoodsSoap(manufactur<strong>in</strong>g)cook<strong>in</strong>goils (ref<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g)GoodModerate,only if R&DdirectedtowardsappropriatetechnologyMedium High StableSimpletraditionalcapital goodsand servicesAgriculturalmechanicalFairSubstantialonly if R&DdirectedcorrectlyMedium High StableSource: Enos, 1998TTs have to be operated <strong>in</strong> many doma<strong>in</strong>s,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g export-oriented <strong>in</strong>dustry. But <strong>the</strong>ymust be particularly supported <strong>in</strong> those doma<strong>in</strong>scorrespond<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> model of <strong>in</strong>novationthat is central to economic growth <strong>in</strong> LDCs.This <strong>in</strong>cludes entrepreneurial activities thatmeet <strong>the</strong> needs of local markets likely togenerate domestic spillover. In o<strong>the</strong>r words,TTs must offer a positive supply responseto a demand for technology stemm<strong>in</strong>g fromlocal entrepreneurs. Two reasons for this areprovided:• First, <strong>the</strong>se doma<strong>in</strong>s are potentiallyimportant for growth because <strong>the</strong> spillovergenerated <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> course of such projects arelikely to be captured by <strong>the</strong> local economy;• Second, <strong>the</strong>se doma<strong>in</strong>s need additional<strong>in</strong>centives so that <strong>the</strong> donor’s <strong>in</strong>terventionwill be effective and will respond fully to<strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> provision. This is not necessarily<strong>the</strong> case of export-oriented sectors <strong>in</strong> which<strong>the</strong> market <strong>in</strong>centives alone are sufficientlystrong to motivate firms <strong>in</strong> rich countries tooperate TTs (see chapter 5 below).2.5 Transactional Modes, Barriers and Incentives 4The major sources of transfer, as described <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>literature (see e.g. Maskus, 2004, World Bank,2008) <strong>in</strong>clude trade, FDI (i.e. MNC), licens<strong>in</strong>g,jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures, and <strong>the</strong> movement of people.Among <strong>the</strong>se various forms of TTs, <strong>the</strong>re aretwo logics to dist<strong>in</strong>guish that make sense when<strong>org</strong>anisational issues, as well as <strong>in</strong>centivesand barriers are considered: packaged andunpackaged forms of TT (Enos et al., 1998).The packaged form essentially means that <strong>the</strong>technology is transferred through FDI, importof goods, or <strong>the</strong> build<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>in</strong>frastructures byforeign firms. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong> transfer oftechnology is a jo<strong>in</strong>t product or a by-productof ano<strong>the</strong>r economic operation. The importanceand quality of TTs are <strong>the</strong>refore cont<strong>in</strong>gent on alarge number of factors result<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>the</strong> primaryeconomic operation. It is thus <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives forsuccess of <strong>the</strong> primary economic operation that


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development21determ<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> motivation for success of <strong>the</strong> TTand its consolidation (or not).Unpackaged is def<strong>in</strong>ed as <strong>the</strong> transfer of atechnology not channelled through direct<strong>in</strong>vestment, trade, or <strong>in</strong>frastructure development.Jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures, licens<strong>in</strong>g, andarrangements <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g technical assistance,collaboration contracts, <strong>in</strong>formal transfer ofknow-how, and consultancy are classified asunpackaged modes of TT. The technologicalknowledge is “disembodied” and transferredthrough software and wetware, not hardware.In this case, <strong>the</strong> TT <strong>in</strong> itself constitutes <strong>the</strong>primary economic operation. Here, <strong>the</strong> primemotivation for <strong>the</strong> operation is <strong>the</strong> success of <strong>the</strong>TT and <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives directly l<strong>in</strong>ked to <strong>the</strong> TT(cost and profit) that control <strong>the</strong> operation. Thema<strong>in</strong> advantage of this mode is that it gives <strong>the</strong>host country control over technology selection,management decisions, and development oflocal skills.Discussion here of TT as a jo<strong>in</strong>t product,by-product or ma<strong>in</strong> operation refers to <strong>the</strong>def<strong>in</strong>ition of <strong>the</strong>se concepts <strong>in</strong> account<strong>in</strong>g.Jo<strong>in</strong>t products are two products that aresimultaneously yielded from one shared costand <strong>the</strong>y have comparably high (sales) value.By-products for <strong>the</strong>ir part are produced alongwith a ma<strong>in</strong> product. The latter constitutes<strong>the</strong> major portion of <strong>the</strong> total (sales) value.By-products have a considerably lower (sales)value than <strong>the</strong>se ma<strong>in</strong> products. These conceptscan be applied to TTs with <strong>the</strong> substitution of“perceived value to technology holders” for“sales value.”It is <strong>the</strong>refore apparent that <strong>the</strong> technologyholder’s commitment may vary considerablydepend<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> TT’s economic operationstatus and <strong>the</strong> importance attributed to it<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> success of <strong>the</strong> primary operation,if it does itself not constitute <strong>the</strong> primaryoperation.In <strong>the</strong> case of TT that is a by-product, <strong>the</strong>technology holder is <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> successof <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> economic operation. Here, realis<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> TT is of secondary importance. In <strong>the</strong> caseof a jo<strong>in</strong>t product, <strong>the</strong> issue is to balance<strong>in</strong>centives between <strong>the</strong> success of <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>reconomic operation (e.g. a direct <strong>in</strong>vestment)and <strong>the</strong> success of <strong>the</strong> TT. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case ofTT as a ma<strong>in</strong> operation, <strong>the</strong> economic <strong>in</strong>centivescannot be allowed to depend on ano<strong>the</strong>reconomic operation. The TT must be sufficientlyattractive <strong>in</strong> itself for <strong>the</strong> technology holder toenter <strong>the</strong> transaction.These three forms of TT (jo<strong>in</strong>t product, byproductand ma<strong>in</strong> operation) are exam<strong>in</strong>edbelow, along with <strong>the</strong> various channels implementedfor each. The <strong>in</strong>centive structure, barriers,limitations, and opportunities associatedwith each type are also exam<strong>in</strong>ed.2.5.1 TT as a jo<strong>in</strong>t producr or by-product: <strong>the</strong> need for balanc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>centivesThis section briefly exam<strong>in</strong>es TT mechanismsas related to trade and direct <strong>in</strong>vestment.In both cases, TT is a jo<strong>in</strong>t product and assuch creates both opportunities for knowledgetransfer and limitations.2.5.1.1 TradeTrade as a channel for TT <strong>in</strong>volves imports ofgoods and services — especially capital goodsand high tech products – and export by firmsfrom lesser developed countries. The role ofhigh tech products and capital goods import asa TT mechanism is clear: it directly impacts <strong>the</strong>domestic economy by improv<strong>in</strong>g productivity andit can foster local <strong>in</strong>novation through reverseeng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g of imported high tech products.Export<strong>in</strong>g goods creates an <strong>in</strong>direct mechanismfor TT. By participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> global value supplycha<strong>in</strong>, LDC firms will benefit from numeroustra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and technological spillover effects from<strong>the</strong>ir customers.One <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g form of trade-related TT issubcontract<strong>in</strong>g, whereby <strong>the</strong> subcontractormanufactures <strong>the</strong> f<strong>in</strong>al product under <strong>the</strong>


22 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economiespr<strong>in</strong>cipal’s brand name (Enos et al., 1998). Thisallows foreign <strong>in</strong>volvement without <strong>the</strong> transferof ownership. Such an arrangement often <strong>in</strong>volves<strong>the</strong> foreign partner <strong>in</strong> select<strong>in</strong>g capital equipment,tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g managers, eng<strong>in</strong>eers and technicians,and advis<strong>in</strong>g on production, f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g, andmanagement. S<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> quality, delivery, andprice of <strong>the</strong> f<strong>in</strong>al product are critical for <strong>the</strong>foreign <strong>in</strong>vestor, this is likely to generate longtermtechnical relationships for capacity build<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> host country. Here <strong>in</strong>centives seem to bealigned. Moreover, learn<strong>in</strong>g and construct<strong>in</strong>gtechnological capabilities often occurs (Hobday,1995). For example, many electronic systemspurchased under this form of TT (subcontract<strong>in</strong>g)were designed, specified, and manufactured by<strong>the</strong> local firm ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> foreign company(see <strong>the</strong> case study on <strong>the</strong> electronics <strong>in</strong>dustryfrom <strong>the</strong> Asian new <strong>in</strong>dustrial economies).The transfer of technology through thisarrangement never<strong>the</strong>less has certa<strong>in</strong>limitations. It is difficult for <strong>the</strong> company <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g country to establish <strong>in</strong>ternationalbrand images. Dependence on foreign companiesfor technologies and components can persist fora long time. On <strong>the</strong> one hand, evidence showsthat substantial learn<strong>in</strong>g can take place throughthis mode. Yet, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, it seems difficultto overcome <strong>the</strong> limitations aris<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>the</strong>dependence of firms <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g economieson this mode of technology acquisition.2.5.1.2 Direct <strong>in</strong>vestmentsA lot of TT occurs through foreign direct<strong>in</strong>vestment. FDI is an efficient transfermechanism because it provides <strong>the</strong> necessary<strong>in</strong>centive and long-term framework to makeTT effective. When FDI is <strong>in</strong>volved, <strong>the</strong>foreign participant has a direct <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>successful TT (Ho, 1997). Consequently, it islikely to participate actively <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> transferprocess, supply<strong>in</strong>g not only equipment andcapital to its foreign affiliate but also highqualitydisembodied knowledge, particularlytacit knowledge such as general technical,bus<strong>in</strong>ess, and managerial know-how. In o<strong>the</strong>rwords, <strong>the</strong> foreign <strong>in</strong>vestor has an <strong>in</strong>centiveto supply much of <strong>the</strong> miss<strong>in</strong>g technical andmanagerial expertise and know-how neededto start up <strong>the</strong> project promptly and help itto rapidly reach its designed production rate.Incentives are aligned.There is abundant empirical literature thatfocuses on <strong>the</strong> dissem<strong>in</strong>ation effects ortechnology spillover from FDI (Blomström andKokko, 1998). Spillover occurs when localfirms benefit from <strong>the</strong> MNC affiliate’s superiorknowledge of technologies without <strong>in</strong>curr<strong>in</strong>g acost that exhausts ga<strong>in</strong>s from improvements.They operate via different mechanisms aselaborated on below:• Backward l<strong>in</strong>kages: This arises from <strong>the</strong> MNCaffiliate’s relationships with local suppliers.Complementary activities developed through<strong>the</strong>se l<strong>in</strong>kages are likely to createspillover effects and several case studieshighlight such positive outcomes. However,<strong>the</strong>y also stress that <strong>the</strong> local content ofMNC production is a strong determ<strong>in</strong>ant ofstrength of l<strong>in</strong>kages.• Forward l<strong>in</strong>kages: This stems from contactswith customers. However, <strong>the</strong>re is muchless evidence of forward than backwardl<strong>in</strong>kages, so that <strong>the</strong> argument po<strong>in</strong>t<strong>in</strong>gtoward <strong>the</strong> existence of FDI spillover towardcustomers is suspicious.• Tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g of local employees <strong>in</strong> MNCaffiliates: Although it is obvious that FDI<strong>in</strong>volves some supply of tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g for localemployees rang<strong>in</strong>g from on-<strong>the</strong>-job tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gto sem<strong>in</strong>ars, and more formal school<strong>in</strong>g tooverseas education, perhaps at <strong>the</strong> parentcompany, <strong>the</strong> evidence on spillover fromMNC affiliate tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g of local employeesis far from complete. There is certa<strong>in</strong>ly anaccumulation of human capital skills <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>MNC’s employee stock. Some of <strong>the</strong>se skillscan be appropriated by local firms whenemployees move to new jobs, but howmuch is an open question.• Demonstration effect: A few case studiessuggest that demonstration (when affiliates’


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development23technology imports have <strong>in</strong>duced localcompetitors to imitate <strong>the</strong>ir behaviour)may be an important channel for spillovers.However, <strong>the</strong>re are too few studies to revealhow important <strong>the</strong> simple demonstrationeffects are.To summarise this literature, potentials forknowledge and technology dissem<strong>in</strong>ation fromFDI are obviously significant. But many conditionsare necessary to realise it fully. Some of <strong>the</strong>seconditions relate to <strong>the</strong> host country: marketsize, local content regulations, and <strong>the</strong> sizeand technological capability of local firms arecountry characteristics that will clearly <strong>in</strong>fluence<strong>the</strong> extent of spillovers.FDI as a vehicle for TT also exhibits someshortcom<strong>in</strong>gs that create challenges for <strong>the</strong>import<strong>in</strong>g country. First, <strong>the</strong> decision concern<strong>in</strong>gwhich technology to transfer and how to<strong>org</strong>anise <strong>the</strong> production of <strong>the</strong> knowledgerequired for development and local adaptationrema<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> hands of <strong>the</strong> foreign <strong>in</strong>vestor.The transferred technology could thusconceivably be <strong>in</strong>appropriate for <strong>the</strong> hostcountry – for <strong>in</strong>stance, too modern for its needsand too capital <strong>in</strong>tensive given <strong>the</strong> resourceendowments of most develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. Itis also likely that foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors will do mostof <strong>the</strong>ir research and development <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>irhome countries, prevent<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> developmentof core technologies <strong>in</strong> host countries (Enoset al., 1998). Will <strong>the</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g economiesget <strong>the</strong> right technologies on <strong>the</strong> right terms?If <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> vehicle for transfer is foreign<strong>in</strong>vestments, <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> TT aspects will notbe decided publicly, via <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>tervention ofgovernment agencies, but privately, by <strong>the</strong>firm. There is <strong>the</strong>refore <strong>the</strong> risk that <strong>the</strong> shiftfrom external and collective to <strong>in</strong>ternal and<strong>in</strong>dividual choice of technology may remove<strong>the</strong> transfer of technology from <strong>the</strong> publicarena (Enos et al., 1998).2.5.1.3 Balanc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>centives: from jo<strong>in</strong>t product to by-productAre <strong>in</strong>centives really aligned (<strong>the</strong> advantagemost frequently advanced)? Foreign <strong>in</strong>vestorsprimarily want to succeed <strong>in</strong> putt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> plant<strong>in</strong>to operation and keep<strong>in</strong>g it runn<strong>in</strong>g for acerta<strong>in</strong> period of time. The success of <strong>the</strong> TT islikely to become of secondary importance.If <strong>in</strong>centives are not properly balanced between<strong>the</strong> need to make <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustrial facilities operateefficiently and <strong>the</strong> need to transfer tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gand knowledge to <strong>the</strong> future local workers andeng<strong>in</strong>eers, it is likely that <strong>the</strong> foreign <strong>in</strong>vestorwill devote <strong>in</strong>sufficient resources and time to <strong>the</strong>learn<strong>in</strong>g process. The whole range of capacitiesand capabilities (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g tacit knowledge)has to be absorbed by <strong>the</strong> nationals of <strong>the</strong>import<strong>in</strong>g country. But what matters most forforeign <strong>in</strong>vestors is <strong>the</strong> success of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustrialoperation and not <strong>the</strong> success of <strong>the</strong> transfer<strong>in</strong> itself. For example, Choii et al. (1994) arguethat foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors have little <strong>in</strong>centive totake <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>itiative <strong>in</strong> shift<strong>in</strong>g responsibility fortechnological adaptations to local suppliersor staff. If <strong>the</strong> replacement of expatriates isunnecessarily delayed, this prevents <strong>the</strong> learn<strong>in</strong>gprocess from fully tak<strong>in</strong>g place. This is a clearcase of unbalanced <strong>in</strong>centives between <strong>the</strong> needto make <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment operational <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> shorttermand <strong>the</strong> need to transfer <strong>the</strong> technology.In this case, TT becomes more like a sort of byproduct(as such a very uneven and unplannedevent) ra<strong>the</strong>r than a jo<strong>in</strong>t product.2.5.2 <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> as Ma<strong>in</strong> operationJo<strong>in</strong>t ventures, licens<strong>in</strong>g, and arrangements forTT as technical assistance, such as collaborationcontracts and <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal transfer of knowhowhave been <strong>the</strong> most popular alternativesto wholly foreign owned MNC subsidiaries assources of technology (Enos et al., 1998). Jo<strong>in</strong>tventures are contractual arrangements betweentwo (or more) firms <strong>in</strong> which each provides someadvantage that should reduce <strong>the</strong> costs of jo<strong>in</strong>toperations. For <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>the</strong> MNC will make <strong>the</strong>new technology available while <strong>the</strong> domesticfirm provides its knowledge of <strong>the</strong> market, <strong>the</strong>regulatory and bus<strong>in</strong>ess environment, and someo<strong>the</strong>r local advantages.


24 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesIn this case, TT is <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> operation and<strong>the</strong>refore <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives are shaped by <strong>the</strong>cost and benefits of <strong>the</strong> TT only. In o<strong>the</strong>rwords, <strong>in</strong>centives cannot be lean<strong>in</strong>g aga<strong>in</strong>stano<strong>the</strong>r economic operation. The TT must beattractive enough for <strong>the</strong> technology holderto enter <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> transaction. As a ma<strong>in</strong>operation, <strong>the</strong> TT provides an opportunity toshift <strong>the</strong> locus of decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g away from<strong>the</strong> foreign bodies to local agents both <strong>in</strong> termsof <strong>the</strong> learn<strong>in</strong>g process and <strong>the</strong> areas <strong>in</strong> whichTTs will operate. TTs as a ma<strong>in</strong> operation give<strong>the</strong> host country control over managementdecisions and <strong>the</strong> development of local skills.This is why many countries have expresseda preference for jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures, with <strong>the</strong>foreign partner <strong>in</strong> a m<strong>in</strong>ority position, overwholly FDI.2.5.2.1 Licens<strong>in</strong>gLicens<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>volves <strong>the</strong> purchase of productionrights, protected by IPRs, and <strong>in</strong> many cases,<strong>the</strong> provision of technical assistance and knowhow,which are needed to adopt and adapt <strong>the</strong>technology. The transfer of tacit knowledge and<strong>the</strong> provision of technical services are centralto ensure that <strong>the</strong> licensor will secure <strong>the</strong>proper capabilities so as to use <strong>the</strong> technology<strong>in</strong> an effective way. For <strong>in</strong>stance, studies oflicens<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> India suggest that Indian firmsimport<strong>in</strong>g technology tend not to receivesufficient amounts of technological know-how.As a result, <strong>the</strong>ir ability to assimilate, utilise,and improve <strong>the</strong> technology is limited. (Arora,1996). Theoretical works (notably by Arora,1995, 1996) demonstrate <strong>the</strong> conditions underwhich know-how can be transferred throughcontracts. One important condition is tobundle know-how transfer with <strong>the</strong> provision ofcomplementary <strong>in</strong>puts.Licens<strong>in</strong>g is becom<strong>in</strong>g central among <strong>the</strong>various market-based channels as marketsfor technology become thicker and more“efficient.” Athreye and Cantwell (2007) f<strong>in</strong>dthat <strong>in</strong>ternational patent licens<strong>in</strong>g and royaltyreceipts have surged s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> mid-1980s. Fromaround USD 10 billion <strong>in</strong> 1984, <strong>in</strong>ternationalpatent licens<strong>in</strong>g and technology receipts grewto more than USD 80 billion <strong>in</strong> 2002 (at currentprices). Over 120 countries reported receiv<strong>in</strong>gsuch royalties and more than 130 countriesreported mak<strong>in</strong>g such payments <strong>in</strong> 2002. Therehas <strong>the</strong>refore obviously been a significant<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational TT through licens<strong>in</strong>goperations (see Arora, 2007, for an up-todateoverview). What is more, this appearsto co<strong>in</strong>cide with an overall streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g ofIP regimes, first <strong>in</strong> rich countries but later <strong>in</strong>poorer countries too.Some countries have pursued a licens<strong>in</strong>gbasedstrategy of technology acquisition <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>belief that it is more favourable to TT and <strong>the</strong>development of learn<strong>in</strong>g capacities by domesticfirms than FDI. Some sparse evidence (Enos etal., 1998) tends to show that jo<strong>in</strong>t venturesprovide greater tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g than licens<strong>in</strong>g, while <strong>the</strong>latter <strong>in</strong>volves greater <strong>in</strong>digenous technologicaleffort.However, one should not f<strong>org</strong>et that marketsfor patents or licenses are not markets fortechnology. Most firms want to purchasetechnologies, not mere patents. For this reason,patents are sold or licensed as part of <strong>the</strong> bundleof goods and services needed to implement atechnology (see Arora’s argument below). Butthis sort of transaction is more complicated andcostly than a mere patent license or assignment.In addition, <strong>in</strong> view of tacit knowledge, and<strong>the</strong> importance of collaborative development,it is unrealistic to expect technology marketsfor today’s complex <strong>in</strong>ventions to function aswell as <strong>the</strong> robust markets dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> heydayof <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong>ventor (Bessen and Meurer,2008). Therefore, <strong>the</strong> various phases of a TT,notably absorption, learn<strong>in</strong>g, adaptation, andassimilation of <strong>the</strong> subsequent improvementsare complex to predict and to plan. Theyare <strong>the</strong>refore difficult to draft as detailedobjectives and milestones <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> contractualarrangement.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development25Figure 1. The Growth of Royalties and Licens<strong>in</strong>g FeesSource: Athreye and Cantwell, 20072.5.2.2 TT as a ma<strong>in</strong> operation: cost and benefitsIn TT as a ma<strong>in</strong> operation, <strong>the</strong>re are no o<strong>the</strong>reconomic operations to “help” and <strong>the</strong> prospectof returns on <strong>the</strong> TT operation must onlybe sufficiently attractive to <strong>in</strong>centivise <strong>the</strong>technology holder to enter <strong>the</strong> transaction.This means that very often additional <strong>in</strong>centivesprovided by governments will be needed(chapter 5, below). But TT as a ma<strong>in</strong> operationoffers opportunities to shift <strong>the</strong> locus for decisionmak<strong>in</strong>gto <strong>the</strong> local agents and domestic firms.When TT is a jo<strong>in</strong>t product of FDI, <strong>the</strong> locus ofdecision-mak<strong>in</strong>g lies <strong>in</strong> foreign firms that decideabout <strong>the</strong> doma<strong>in</strong>, <strong>the</strong> modes of learn<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>the</strong>amount of resources devoted to <strong>the</strong> TT operation,<strong>the</strong> potential scope of fur<strong>the</strong>r dissem<strong>in</strong>ation,<strong>the</strong> objectives of assimilat<strong>in</strong>g subsequentimprovements, and etc. Clearly, when <strong>the</strong> locusof decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g regard<strong>in</strong>g areas for TTs lieswith foreign firms, <strong>the</strong>re is a risk of a suboptimaldecision process (see <strong>the</strong> argument above <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>case of FDI). 5When <strong>the</strong> TT is <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> operation, <strong>the</strong>re ismuch more flexibility about who will make <strong>the</strong>ma<strong>in</strong> decisions: domestic bodies (entrepreneurs,governmental agencies), foreign donors or foreignfirms. The argument is that <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> circumstancesof TT as <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> product, <strong>the</strong> locus of decisionmak<strong>in</strong>gshould not be kept <strong>in</strong> foreign assistancebodies but transferred to local government<strong>in</strong>itiatives and entrepreneurs. This is particularlyimportant for decisions that concern:• The mode of learn<strong>in</strong>g and <strong>the</strong> “quality” ofTT. To what extent conditions for effectivelearn<strong>in</strong>g and transfer of capabilities will be<strong>org</strong>anised by <strong>the</strong> technology holder? and;• The choice of areas to be concentrated on.TTs address specific knowledge areas andtechnological trajectories. The issue of selection<strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g both priority-sett<strong>in</strong>g andtechnology forecast<strong>in</strong>g must be addresseds<strong>in</strong>ce it is a critical one: a successful TT, ifnot done <strong>in</strong> a relevant area for <strong>the</strong> countryconsidered, will produce very little benefit.It is thus imperative to critically exam<strong>in</strong>e<strong>the</strong> conditions and procedures of prioritysett<strong>in</strong>gand technology selection. Section2.4 above already clarified <strong>in</strong> what doma<strong>in</strong>sTTs should be undertaken first. Thisargument will be fully developed below (<strong>in</strong>chapter 5).


26 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economies2.5.3 <strong>Technology</strong> transfer without compensation: imitation and reverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>gWhat dist<strong>in</strong>guishes this mode of operation fromlicens<strong>in</strong>g and jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures is that imitation doesnot entail any compensation to <strong>the</strong> technologyowner. This does not mean that it is a costlessprocess, however. Imitation can be very complex– it takes time and resources, which makes itperfectly tolerable from a competition po<strong>in</strong>tof view. The <strong>in</strong>itial <strong>in</strong>ventor can use <strong>the</strong> “leadtime” (<strong>the</strong> gap between <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vention and <strong>the</strong>entry of imitators) to capture a large fraction of<strong>the</strong> benefits and <strong>the</strong>reby cover R&D fixed costs.Be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> first is an asset that can command apositive price under competitive conditions. Thisprice reflects <strong>the</strong> present value of <strong>the</strong> futureflow of marg<strong>in</strong>al utilities that subsequent copieswill yield to impatient consumers because <strong>the</strong>process of imitation takes time.It is because imitation is time consum<strong>in</strong>g andcostly that Samuelson and Scotchmer (2001)argue that reverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g has generallybeen considered a positive element for foster<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>novation and <strong>the</strong> transfer of knowledge. Reverseeng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g is fundamentally directed todiscovery and <strong>in</strong>novation. Eng<strong>in</strong>eers learn <strong>the</strong>state of <strong>the</strong> art not only by read<strong>in</strong>g publications,go<strong>in</strong>g to conferences, and work<strong>in</strong>g on projects,but also by reverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g o<strong>the</strong>rs’ products.Learn<strong>in</strong>g what has been done before often leadsto new products and advances <strong>in</strong> know-how. Ifreverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g is costly and takes time, asis usually <strong>the</strong> case, <strong>in</strong>novators will be protectedlong enough to recoup R&D expenses. As such, itis a competitively healthy way for second comersto access and discern <strong>the</strong> know-how embedded<strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>novator’s product.Samuelson and Scotchmer (ibid.) also arguethat <strong>the</strong> very act of reverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g rarely(if ever) has destructive effects on <strong>the</strong> market.Harmful effects are far more likely to resultfrom post-reverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g activities, suchas sell<strong>in</strong>g a compet<strong>in</strong>g product made with knowhowfrom an <strong>in</strong>novator’s product. Because ofthis differentiation, policy has at least to ignore<strong>the</strong> act of reverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g while focus<strong>in</strong>g onregulatory controls on market-destructive postreverse-eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g activities.2.6 Brief SummaryThis section has put a framework <strong>in</strong> place basedon two key taxonomies:• The phases of TTs: absorption, adaptation,assimilation of subsequent improvements,and dissem<strong>in</strong>ation (spillovers); and• The economic nature of TTs: by-product,jo<strong>in</strong>t product, or ma<strong>in</strong> operation.When <strong>the</strong> TT is a jo<strong>in</strong>t product (occurr<strong>in</strong>g as aconsequence of a direct <strong>in</strong>vestment), <strong>the</strong> phasesof absorption, adaptation, and assimilationof subsequent improvements are <strong>in</strong> a senseembedded <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment project. However,s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> TT is a jo<strong>in</strong>t product, <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>the</strong>problem of “balanc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>centives” between <strong>the</strong>need to make <strong>the</strong> direct <strong>in</strong>vestment operationaland profitable <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> short-term, and <strong>the</strong> need totransfer technologies and capabilities. Indeed,<strong>the</strong> risk of a strong imbalance aris<strong>in</strong>g between<strong>the</strong>se two <strong>in</strong>centives is considerable <strong>in</strong> LDCss<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> cost of transferr<strong>in</strong>g technologies andbuild<strong>in</strong>g capabilities is high. As a result, foreignfirms are tempted to limit <strong>the</strong> scope and depthof <strong>the</strong> transfer of technologies and capabilities<strong>in</strong> order to <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>the</strong> short-term profitabilityof <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment. In such a case, <strong>the</strong> TT is nolonger a jo<strong>in</strong>t product but becomes a by-product– that is to say a negligible objective.When TT is <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> operation, <strong>the</strong> problem isthat <strong>in</strong>centives cannot be allowed to dependon ano<strong>the</strong>r economic operation. The TT, <strong>in</strong>that case, does not offer o<strong>the</strong>r benefits to <strong>the</strong>technology holder than what is generated through<strong>the</strong> transaction. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, it providesopportunities to shift <strong>the</strong> locus of decisionmak<strong>in</strong>gtoward local authorities and agents both<strong>in</strong> terms of <strong>the</strong> choice of areas for focus and <strong>the</strong>mode of learn<strong>in</strong>g to be implemented.In both cases (jo<strong>in</strong>t product and ma<strong>in</strong> operation),<strong>the</strong> broad dissem<strong>in</strong>ation of <strong>the</strong> technology and<strong>the</strong> spillovers stemm<strong>in</strong>g from a given TT locusare not guaranteed. The successful achievement


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development27of this f<strong>in</strong>al phase of <strong>the</strong> TT requires particular<strong>org</strong>anisational forms.This also underl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong> peculiar nature of<strong>in</strong>novation <strong>in</strong> LDCs that TTs have to serve(demand side). The centrality of a particularmodel of <strong>in</strong>novation for growth and developmenthas already been emphasised. R&D and o<strong>the</strong>rmore <strong>in</strong>formal learn<strong>in</strong>g activities undertaken toproduce locally oriented <strong>in</strong>novations allow <strong>the</strong>country to develop absorptive capacity, while at<strong>the</strong> same time <strong>the</strong> locally generated spilloversfrom this same R&D may end up diffus<strong>in</strong>g awayfrom <strong>the</strong> local economy. TT as a ma<strong>in</strong> operationprovides <strong>the</strong> opportunity to target those areas<strong>in</strong> which such <strong>in</strong>novative activities can beundertaken.Chapter 4 uses recent evidence to observe<strong>the</strong> mechanisms (<strong>in</strong> particular FDI, trade andlicens<strong>in</strong>g) that are effectively operat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>LDC context and <strong>the</strong>ir relative importance andimpact on economic growth and development <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong>se countries.


28 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economies3. TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS3.1 The Conditions for <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> to LDCs under <strong>TRIPS</strong>As a new <strong>in</strong>ternational system of IP protectionhas slowly been implemented as part of WTOAgreements to guarantee <strong>the</strong> enforceabilityof IPRs globally, policy discussions have beenre<strong>in</strong>vigorated. This places significant pressureon countries that decided one or more decadesago to limit <strong>the</strong> scope of IP protection tofacilitate knowledge access for both immediateconsumption (drugs) and learn<strong>in</strong>g (technologicalknowledge).3.1.1 An overview of <strong>TRIPS</strong>The <strong>TRIPS</strong> Agreement establishes global mandatorym<strong>in</strong>imum standards for <strong>the</strong> grant<strong>in</strong>gand protection of IP rights <strong>in</strong> several areas,particularly copyrights and patents. It alsoprovides for strong enforcement measures anda settlement of disputes mechanism. Countriesare free to decide how to implement <strong>the</strong>seprovisions accord<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong>ir own legal systemand practices. The application of <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries has been mandatory s<strong>in</strong>ce2000, except for technologies not previouslyprotected by-product patents. However, LDCsare benefit<strong>in</strong>g from a transition period until2013, with a fur<strong>the</strong>r extension until 2016 forpharmaceutical products.Both <strong>the</strong> US and EU benefit economically fromstronger foreign IP rights, as this streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>gwill lead to an <strong>in</strong>creased flow of royalties orprofits <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> enterta<strong>in</strong>ment, pharmaceutical,and o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>dustries. The <strong>in</strong>troduction of aglobal system to enforce IPRs is a positivedevelopment for mult<strong>in</strong>ational companies aswell, which expect an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> profitabilityof <strong>the</strong>ir R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments. These <strong>in</strong>dustriesare <strong>the</strong>refore plac<strong>in</strong>g strong pressure on <strong>the</strong>negotiators of <strong>the</strong> developed nations. Hence<strong>the</strong>re is a sense that if stronger IPRs cannot benegotiated at <strong>the</strong> World Intellectual PropertyOrganisation (WIPO) or <strong>the</strong> WTO, <strong>the</strong>y shouldbe obta<strong>in</strong>ed via bilateral agreements. While<strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> Agreement established m<strong>in</strong>imumstandards of IP protection for WTO Members,substantial efforts are be<strong>in</strong>g made, particularlyby <strong>the</strong> United States, to negotiate bilateralarrangements to limit part of <strong>the</strong> autonomy leftto develop<strong>in</strong>g countries by <strong>TRIPS</strong> to go beyondits required levels of IP protection, <strong>the</strong>rebystreng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g IP rights.On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong> official <strong>TRIPS</strong> messageis that develop<strong>in</strong>g countries should considerthis legal obligation as a positive arrangement.In a knowledge economy, strong IPRs arepresented as beneficial for develop<strong>in</strong>g countries<strong>the</strong>mselves s<strong>in</strong>ce this evolution will create<strong>in</strong>centives for <strong>the</strong> endogenous development ofdomestic entrepreneurial capacities and help<strong>the</strong>se countries to attract more FDI and absorband acquire more foreign technologies throughlicens<strong>in</strong>g and o<strong>the</strong>r market-based transactions.It is time to revisit this economic discussionwith<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> new context of a global IPR systemunder construction. Regard<strong>in</strong>g TTs, <strong>the</strong> questionis how IP protection effects <strong>the</strong> different transfermodes as described above. There are two relatedquestions here: first, how does patent protectionaffect TT with<strong>in</strong> a given mode? Second, how doespatent protection affect <strong>the</strong> choice between<strong>the</strong>se modes? Arora (2007) suggests that <strong>the</strong>relative importance of <strong>the</strong> different sources mayvary over time, and that IP protection may affect<strong>the</strong>se sources differently.3.1.2 Transformation of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional conditions for TTs under <strong>TRIPS</strong>Maskus (2004) proposes a dist<strong>in</strong>ction between“market-based forms of TT” (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g FDI,technologies embodied <strong>in</strong> imported goods,licens<strong>in</strong>g, exports by firms <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> recipientcountry) and “non-market-based forms of TT”(<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g imitation and reverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g,learn<strong>in</strong>g from patents filed by foreign <strong>in</strong>ventors,learn<strong>in</strong>g from scientific publications, movementof workers and students, and o<strong>the</strong>r types ofspillovers). Maskus (2004) shows that certa<strong>in</strong>“market-based” channels have <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>importance over time.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development29Simple reason<strong>in</strong>g, plus some sparse empiricalstudies, would allow <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g developmentsto be identified. The streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of IPprotection can be expected to result <strong>in</strong> an<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> relative importance of licencesand direct <strong>in</strong>vestments, and <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> quasidisappearanceof imitation. It can also be anticipatedthat with<strong>in</strong> a specific mode – suchas, direct <strong>in</strong>vestment – <strong>the</strong> TT will be moresuccessful <strong>in</strong>sofar as a streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of IPprotection will <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>the</strong> technology holder’s<strong>in</strong>centives to transfer <strong>in</strong> an efficient manner.Some transfer modes would thus practicallydisappear, while o<strong>the</strong>rs would be streng<strong>the</strong>ned.The <strong>TRIPS</strong> philosophy is basically to reduce <strong>the</strong>range of transfer modes, whilst consolidat<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>stitutions that facilitate a small number ofmodes, at <strong>the</strong> risk of elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g o<strong>the</strong>rs (seeBox 4).Box 4. <strong>TRIPS</strong> and <strong>the</strong> Public Doma<strong>in</strong> of Knowledge<strong>TRIPS</strong> has considerable potential to <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>the</strong> “excludability” of R&D results andreduce knowledge diffusion and <strong>in</strong>formational spillovers (Foray, 2004).By focus<strong>in</strong>g on licens<strong>in</strong>g as <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> means of transferr<strong>in</strong>g technology, <strong>TRIPS</strong> isconceptually based on a narrow view of <strong>the</strong> channels through which knowledge candiffuse. In reality, <strong>the</strong>se channels are multiple and all contribute to <strong>the</strong> transfer ofknowledge, while <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives created by <strong>TRIPS</strong> promote only one channel (patent<strong>in</strong>gand licences), entail<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> risk of block<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs. Focus<strong>in</strong>g exclusively on provid<strong>in</strong>gbetter IP protection is likely to cause serious collateral damage to o<strong>the</strong>r complementary<strong>in</strong>stitutions that support TTs <strong>in</strong> different ways.The fact that <strong>the</strong> diversity of <strong>in</strong>stitutional arrangements is threatened constitutes acause for concern. Traditionally, IPRs are considered as one of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive structuressociety employs to encourage <strong>in</strong>novative effort. They co-exist with o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>centivestructures, each of which <strong>in</strong>volves costs and benefits as well as a certa<strong>in</strong> degree ofcomplementarities. The new view is that IPRs are <strong>the</strong> preferred means of commodify<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>tangible capital represented by knowledge, and should <strong>the</strong>refore be seen as acommon currency or “yardstick” for measur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> output of activities devoted toknowledge generation and <strong>the</strong> foundation for markets <strong>in</strong> knowledge exchange.The space for public research and knowledge shar<strong>in</strong>g is shr<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g and functions thatwere assumed by <strong>the</strong> public doma<strong>in</strong> are no longer assumed at <strong>the</strong> same level. In short,recent decades have seen <strong>the</strong> emergence of a pronounced worldwide trend towards <strong>the</strong>commoditisation of publicly funded research outputs, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g underly<strong>in</strong>g data and<strong>in</strong>formation resources.It is also advisable to exam<strong>in</strong>e to what extentTT modes are entirely <strong>in</strong>terchangeable from<strong>the</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t of view of <strong>the</strong>ir effectiveness,especially for LDCs. If this were <strong>the</strong> case, <strong>the</strong>n<strong>the</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of IP protection would notradically affect <strong>the</strong> capacity of <strong>the</strong>se countriesto assimilate and absorb new technologies. If,on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, this is not <strong>the</strong> case <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of IP protection could seriouslyaffect <strong>the</strong> capacity of certa<strong>in</strong> countries toabsorb <strong>the</strong> technologies <strong>the</strong>y need. Countriesextensively us<strong>in</strong>g imitation as TT mode are lesswell placed with regard to direct <strong>in</strong>vestmentsor licens<strong>in</strong>g, for example.3.2 The Impact of <strong>TRIPS</strong> on <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>It has been argued for a long time by develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries (and many economists) that <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>ternational IP system was biased aga<strong>in</strong>st <strong>the</strong>m.This argument was essentially a distributional orequity argument: poor countries, at <strong>the</strong>ir stage ofdevelopment, ought not to be obliged to pay forknowledge that would ultimately become part ofmank<strong>in</strong>d’s universal heritage. Along <strong>the</strong>se l<strong>in</strong>es,India and Brazil, among o<strong>the</strong>r countries, passedlaws restrict<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> scope of IP protection. 7


30 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesA ra<strong>the</strong>r different rationale is based on <strong>the</strong>idea that s<strong>in</strong>ce, <strong>in</strong> most cases, <strong>the</strong> markets ofdevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries were not those for whichpatent holders had targeted, <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>in</strong>novationsand profits deriv<strong>in</strong>g from sales represent pureeconomic rents. So that while it might be debatedas a matter of equity that as beneficiaries <strong>the</strong>yshould pay, or that be<strong>in</strong>g poor <strong>the</strong>y should notbe asked to pay, <strong>the</strong> important fact rema<strong>in</strong>sthat it would not make much difference from anefficiency standpo<strong>in</strong>t: <strong>the</strong> world’s supply of such<strong>in</strong>novations would not be much dim<strong>in</strong>ished – ifat all – by <strong>the</strong>se countries adopt<strong>in</strong>g a free rid<strong>in</strong>gpolicy. The more recent growth <strong>in</strong> consciousnessregard<strong>in</strong>g global market<strong>in</strong>g possibilities hastended to vitiate this l<strong>in</strong>e of rationalisation.The pros and cons of <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>TRIPS</strong> on <strong>the</strong>capacity of develop<strong>in</strong>g countries to perform TTsare systematically discussed below.3.2.1 <strong>TRIPS</strong> barriers and obstacles to LDCs perform<strong>in</strong>g technology transfersMany TTs occur through <strong>in</strong>voluntary dissem<strong>in</strong>ationvia copy<strong>in</strong>g and reverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g.Such mechanisms are perfectly acceptablefrom a competition policy po<strong>in</strong>t of view whenoperations are complex and demand resourcesand time (see below). The technology holderdoes not participate <strong>in</strong> this transfer, and <strong>in</strong> manycases, seeks to restrict it. Dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> periodof no – or moderate – IPR <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> LDCs, copy<strong>in</strong>gwas certa<strong>in</strong>ly a major channel for TT. One canargue that it is plausible that today stronger IPRsmay retard such transfer while streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g“market-based” channels. 8The fact that copy<strong>in</strong>g and reverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>grequire more complex and sophisticated legalconditions might be a significant problemfor develop<strong>in</strong>g countries; a problem whosemagnitude can be realised just by recall<strong>in</strong>g thatmost rich countries have used this mechanism asa ma<strong>in</strong> strategy for technological improvementsand growth. For a while Switzerland, for<strong>in</strong>stance, excluded all <strong>in</strong>ventions <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> chemicalfield from patentability. Such a decision wasexpla<strong>in</strong>ed by <strong>the</strong> difficult position of <strong>the</strong> youngSwiss chemical <strong>in</strong>dustry, unable to competewith German firms that had a large-scaleadvantage. The Swiss chemical <strong>in</strong>dustry adopteda strategy based on two pillars: <strong>in</strong>novation andimitation/variation. It focused on products withhigh-added value, especially medic<strong>in</strong>es. Thisstrategy was backed by a policy of imitation.The absence of regulations concern<strong>in</strong>g patentsfor <strong>the</strong> Swiss chemical <strong>in</strong>dustry allowed <strong>the</strong>Basel firms to concentrate <strong>the</strong>ir resources onimitat<strong>in</strong>g procedures developed abroad. It wasonly <strong>in</strong> 1907 that a patent law worthy of <strong>the</strong>name came <strong>in</strong>to be<strong>in</strong>g as a consequence of <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>dustry’s chang<strong>in</strong>g attitude. The development of<strong>the</strong> Swiss chemical firms made <strong>the</strong>m <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>glydependent on <strong>in</strong>novation through <strong>the</strong>ir own R&Dactivities and less on imitation and learn<strong>in</strong>g bydo<strong>in</strong>g. Under <strong>the</strong>se conditions, a patent lawbecame important for <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry. With<strong>in</strong> a fewdecades, <strong>the</strong> accusation of piracy was f<strong>org</strong>ottenand <strong>the</strong> Swiss chemical <strong>in</strong>dustry became knownfor <strong>the</strong> quality of its products.What k<strong>in</strong>d of catch<strong>in</strong>g-up and knowledgeaccess mechanisms does <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternationalgovernance system leave LDCs when copy<strong>in</strong>gis becom<strong>in</strong>g legally more difficult? What is <strong>the</strong>alternative? And, what are <strong>the</strong> mechanismsthat could replace copy<strong>in</strong>g? These are importantquestions s<strong>in</strong>ce copy<strong>in</strong>g and reverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>gproved historically to have two virtues fordevelopment.First, it allows immediate and free access toessential knowledge. Second, it facilitates <strong>the</strong>build<strong>in</strong>g of productive capacities and <strong>in</strong>dustriallearn<strong>in</strong>g, as already expla<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Swiss case.Ano<strong>the</strong>r example is <strong>the</strong> Indian Patent Act <strong>in</strong> 1970that made pharmaceutical product <strong>in</strong>novationsunpatentable, allow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>novations to be copiedand marketed <strong>in</strong> India. Regard<strong>in</strong>g pharmaceuticalprocess patents, <strong>the</strong> statutory term was shortenedto seven years and automatic licens<strong>in</strong>g wasput <strong>in</strong> place. As a result, Indian <strong>in</strong>dustry learnedvery fast: Indian firms accounted for 70 percent of <strong>the</strong> bulk drug market. Of <strong>the</strong> top tenfirms, based on 1996 pharmaceutical sales, sixwere Indian ra<strong>the</strong>r than subsidiaries of foreignmult<strong>in</strong>ationals (Lanjouw, 1998). Cassier andCorrea (2005) made a careful empirical studyof <strong>the</strong> anti-retroviral copy<strong>in</strong>g project <strong>in</strong> Brazil,


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development31show<strong>in</strong>g evidence of technological learn<strong>in</strong>g as aresult of copy<strong>in</strong>g.Now that <strong>TRIPS</strong> makes copy<strong>in</strong>g and reverseeng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g more difficult, <strong>the</strong>re is still <strong>the</strong>problem of devis<strong>in</strong>g new mechanisms to address<strong>the</strong>se issues: how to preserve free and immediateaccess to essential knowledge for passiveconsumption, and how to ensure free access totechnological knowledge for active contributionto <strong>in</strong>cremental improvements, local <strong>in</strong>novations,and capacity build<strong>in</strong>g?New evidence tends to suggest that if strongerIP protection slows down imitation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> South,this is offset by an <strong>in</strong>crease of mult<strong>in</strong>ationalactivities (such as FDI), suggest<strong>in</strong>g an overallenhancement of <strong>in</strong>dustrial development <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries (Branstetter et al., 2007).But while it might be true for a certa<strong>in</strong> categoryof develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, it is certa<strong>in</strong>ly not truefor <strong>the</strong> poorest. It is <strong>the</strong>refore necessary toreview <strong>the</strong> pros and cons with regard to <strong>TRIPS</strong>impact on TT and to qualify <strong>the</strong>se arguments for<strong>the</strong> particular case of LDCs.3.2.2 Stronger IPRs are needed to support technology transferThere is a well-known set of arguments basedon <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical view that IP protection isan <strong>in</strong>centive mechanism that rewards andmotivates <strong>in</strong>novative activities and as such isan <strong>in</strong>dispensable component of a TT-friendlysystem. With some nuances, this argument isperfectly plausible and acceptable for <strong>the</strong> caseof develop<strong>in</strong>g countries that are clearly catch<strong>in</strong>gup(see Arora, 2007, for <strong>the</strong> most recent paperon this subject). It is likely, however, that sucharguments do not apply to <strong>the</strong> reality of a numberof develop<strong>in</strong>g countries and particularly LDCs.Export and parallel trade issues would alsoarise with respect to goods produced undersuspension of <strong>in</strong>dustrial design protection.Because countries protect <strong>in</strong>dustrial designwith different legal mechanisms and becausea wide spectrum of goods may be protected by<strong>in</strong>dustrial design, it is difficult to generalisewith respect to <strong>the</strong> specific type of exhaustionissues that would be presented. If exportswere to be undertaken, this would <strong>in</strong> anyevent be <strong>in</strong>cluded with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> calculation of<strong>the</strong> level of suspension.3.2.2.1 Attract<strong>in</strong>g foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestments and promot<strong>in</strong>g domesticentrepreneurial activitiesIt is claimed that where <strong>the</strong> IP protection regimeis weak, FDI is discouraged, and that when<strong>in</strong>vestments do occur, <strong>the</strong>y are more likely tobe conf<strong>in</strong>ed to wholly-owned subsidiaries or <strong>the</strong>transfer of older technologies. But, aga<strong>in</strong>, <strong>the</strong>searguments need qualifications.First, many factors <strong>in</strong>fluence FDI decisions and<strong>the</strong>re is little empirical evidence to support<strong>the</strong> assertion that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>security of <strong>in</strong>tellectualproperty exerts powerful adverse effects on<strong>the</strong>m. The fact that <strong>the</strong> type of R&D undertaken<strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, be<strong>in</strong>g less <strong>in</strong>novative,is not sensitive to patent protection must beconsidered here. There are exceptions, notably<strong>the</strong> chemical and pharmaceutical <strong>in</strong>dustries,<strong>in</strong> which <strong>the</strong> host country’s IP regime doessignificantly effect FDI decisions and levels<strong>in</strong> R&D facilities (Mansfield, 1995). But <strong>the</strong>se<strong>in</strong>dustries are not many. They are those where<strong>the</strong> centrality of patent as a mechanism toreward <strong>in</strong>novators has been observed for a longtime. 9Second, as already noted, FDI by mult<strong>in</strong>ationals<strong>in</strong> wholly-owned subsidiaries is considered tobe, at best, a somewhat uncerta<strong>in</strong> channelfor transferr<strong>in</strong>g technological knowledge andempower<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>digenous <strong>in</strong>dustries withtechnological capabilities (see above chapter 2,2.5.1.2). Therefore, it seems more relevant toconsider how <strong>the</strong> efficacy of o<strong>the</strong>r TT modes,such as jo<strong>in</strong>t venture and arms-length licens<strong>in</strong>gagreements, are affected by <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong>prevail<strong>in</strong>g IP regime.Ano<strong>the</strong>r possible positive <strong>in</strong>fluence of strongerIPRs concerns entrepreneurial <strong>in</strong>itiatives <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> LDC itself. Entrepreneurs, like any o<strong>the</strong>reconomic agents, respond to <strong>in</strong>centives. They will


32 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economiesstart bus<strong>in</strong>esses and develop new applications of<strong>the</strong> technology if <strong>the</strong> expected private returnsassociated with <strong>the</strong>se creative activities aresufficiently high, i.e. higher than those promisedby o<strong>the</strong>r (less productive) k<strong>in</strong>ds of bus<strong>in</strong>ess.Clearly, stronger patent laws contribute positivelyto private returns on <strong>in</strong>novation. For<strong>in</strong>stance, secur<strong>in</strong>g mechanisms to capture <strong>the</strong>economic rents created by <strong>in</strong>novation will change<strong>the</strong> pay-off structure of <strong>the</strong> economy to make<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>novation a highly profitableactivity, so that entrepreneurial activities –previously developed <strong>in</strong> non-productive areas– will be reallocated to productive areas suchas technology development. Alas, while this<strong>the</strong>ory may apply <strong>in</strong> rich and middle-advancedcountries, it will not <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of LDCs.Many o<strong>the</strong>r problems have to be solved beforestronger patents will start to have an impacton entrepreneurial <strong>in</strong>centives <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> domesticeconomy. Without good <strong>in</strong>frastructure, <strong>the</strong> ruleof law, and well educated people, patents alonewill not do <strong>the</strong> job.In o<strong>the</strong>r words, if an LDC is seek<strong>in</strong>g to attractmore FDI and promot<strong>in</strong>g entrepreneurial activitiesat home, it needs to solve many difficultproblems related to <strong>in</strong>vestment climate, efficientgovernance, market size and <strong>in</strong>frastructurebefore deal<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>the</strong> patent issue. Thus, <strong>the</strong>relevant policy question is to ask at what stageof development economic and market-based<strong>in</strong>centives (such as patents) become importantto <strong>in</strong>cite productive entrepreneurial activitiesand attract more FDI.Hall (2005) summarises this discussion asfollows:i) Throughout history, a stronger patentsystem has tended to be <strong>the</strong> result oftechnological development and <strong>the</strong> creationof firms capable of tak<strong>in</strong>g advantage of<strong>the</strong>se systems, and not a precondition.ii)Stronger patent rights are likely to <strong>in</strong>creasepayments from develop<strong>in</strong>g to developedcountries for technology rights.iii) International trade flows and FDI respondpositively to streng<strong>the</strong>ned patent rights<strong>in</strong> middle-<strong>in</strong>come and large develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries, but not <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> poorest ones(Branstetter et al., 2005).Aga<strong>in</strong>, <strong>the</strong> argument here concerns <strong>the</strong> leastdeveloped countries. Regard<strong>in</strong>g a few majorcatch<strong>in</strong>g-up economies, <strong>the</strong> current alignmentof national patent and regulatory systemswith those of developed countries is basedon <strong>the</strong> belief that such alignment is usefulfor attract<strong>in</strong>g foreign capital and, to a lesserextent, that it might stimulate local <strong>in</strong>novationand entrepreneurships (see chapter 4 below andAbbott, 2003).3.2.2.2 Structur<strong>in</strong>g complex transaction on knowledgeOne argument that has attracted attention,<strong>in</strong>itially voiced by Arora (1995) <strong>in</strong>volves<strong>the</strong> role of IP protection <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> creation oftechnological capabilities associated with atransfer of technologies. The argument goesas follows: to be successful, a TT must take<strong>in</strong>to account <strong>the</strong> complementary role of tacitknowledge, which is absolutely necessary to“activate” <strong>the</strong> technology <strong>in</strong> an economicallysusta<strong>in</strong>able way. The association of <strong>the</strong> transferof this tacit knowledge (through technologysupport and tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g services) with <strong>the</strong> transferof <strong>the</strong> technology itself requires <strong>the</strong> design ofspecific contracts. While <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetriesand monitor<strong>in</strong>g difficulties make itvirtually impossible to draft efficient contractsspecify<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> transfer of tacit knowledge, it ispossible to design contracts for <strong>the</strong> successfulimplementation of technologies by bundl<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> provision of assistance toge<strong>the</strong>r with <strong>the</strong>licens<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> use of codified <strong>in</strong>formation suchas patent and copyrights (Arora, 1995).In such cases, patents play a significant role<strong>in</strong> help<strong>in</strong>g to structure a complex transaction<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g unpatented knowledge.If <strong>the</strong> protection for such property is weak <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> borrow<strong>in</strong>g country however, <strong>the</strong> orig<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>gfirm is unlikely to enter <strong>in</strong>to such contracts.The implication of this is clear: <strong>the</strong> wouldbeborrowers have an <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> a stronger IP


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development33protection regime. This argument tells us that<strong>the</strong> South will ga<strong>in</strong> from extend<strong>in</strong>g IP protection<strong>in</strong>to its own markets by focus<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> conditionsfor <strong>the</strong> successful transfer of codified and tacitknowledge regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>novations.The argument developed by Arora (1995)is a sophisticated one. It is based on <strong>the</strong>transactional difficulties created by <strong>the</strong> factthat codified <strong>in</strong>formation and tacit knowledgeare complementary and must be transferredtoge<strong>the</strong>r. However, this argument overlooks <strong>the</strong>problem of legal and technical capacities of<strong>the</strong> recipient country that needs, <strong>in</strong> particular,highly skilled people able to deal with complexcontract negotiations.3.2.2.3 Structur<strong>in</strong>g and provid<strong>in</strong>g free technical <strong>in</strong>formation, while not imped<strong>in</strong>gaccess and transfer “to certa<strong>in</strong> countries”F<strong>in</strong>ally, “copy<strong>in</strong>g” as a TT mechanism is notnecessarily impeded or prohibited <strong>in</strong> a strongIP environment but can, on <strong>the</strong> contrary, beenhanced <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> special circumstances.First, it is useful to recall that <strong>in</strong> exchange forpatent rights, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ventor must publicly divulgetechnical details of <strong>the</strong> new technologicalknowledge. Technical description is an essentialact. It is <strong>in</strong>tended to provide sufficient “<strong>in</strong>structions”for a specialist <strong>in</strong> that particular field tobe able to reproduce <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vention. In this sense,<strong>the</strong> patent system generates a huge repositoryof technical <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> any technologicalarea that can be freely used by anyone look<strong>in</strong>gfor <strong>in</strong>formation about a given technology. It may<strong>the</strong>n happen that <strong>the</strong> patents provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> useful<strong>in</strong>formation are not valid <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> countries sothat not only can <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation be freely used,but also <strong>the</strong> knowledge can be reproduced andused commercially <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se countries.This is exactly what happened <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia wherecerta<strong>in</strong> technologies were needed to develophear<strong>in</strong>g aids powered by solar energy. A searchwas carried out for patent documents relatedto hear<strong>in</strong>g aids, which enabled <strong>the</strong> retrieval ofa number of <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g documents. Detailedanalysis revealed that all <strong>the</strong>se documents relatedto patents that did not protect <strong>the</strong> disclosed<strong>in</strong>ventions <strong>in</strong> any African countries. Therefore,<strong>the</strong> published patent documents conta<strong>in</strong>edtechnical <strong>in</strong>formation that could be freely used<strong>in</strong> Africa for solv<strong>in</strong>g technical problems, and <strong>the</strong>disclosed devices could be freely manufacturedand distributed <strong>in</strong> Africa (Corsi, 2007).This case exemplifies an ideal situation<strong>in</strong> which <strong>the</strong> IP system provides a strongmechanism to structure <strong>in</strong>formation and<strong>in</strong>creases <strong>the</strong> productivity of <strong>in</strong>formationsearch, while not imped<strong>in</strong>g access to <strong>the</strong>knowledge once retrieved. It is important toknow whe<strong>the</strong>r this case represents a generalpattern – i.e. <strong>the</strong>re are many granted patentsfor which <strong>the</strong> applicants have no <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>African markets and consequently will neverapply for correspond<strong>in</strong>g protection – or whe<strong>the</strong>rit is quite exceptional. 10There is <strong>the</strong>refore an obvious need for<strong>in</strong>ternational collaboration to establish IP<strong>in</strong>formation systems and clear<strong>in</strong>g houses. Such asystem could greatly reduce <strong>the</strong> cost of patentsearches by develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. There arealready a few examples of <strong>in</strong>ternet-based patentdatabases that enable a user to easily access andanalyse published patents and patent applicationsfrom many countries (Byerlee and Fischer, 2002).This mechanism, sometimes called “unilateralaccess” has a number of limitations however,even when it is strictly legal (ibid.).3.3 Markets For <strong>Technology</strong>: Are They Really Efficient?In an ideal world where all entities are at <strong>the</strong>same level of technological advancement, it canbe hypo<strong>the</strong>sised that <strong>the</strong> technology market,based on a strong and respected IPRs system,offers a very effective mode of TT. This is Baumol’s<strong>the</strong>ory, supported by empirical evidence fromArora et al. (2001): IP creates transferable rightsand can also help to structure complex markettransactions <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g technologies.Baumol (2002) argues that firms are remarkablyquick to transfer <strong>the</strong>ir technologies, which can


34 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economiesbe expla<strong>in</strong>ed by capitalist <strong>in</strong>centives as wellas <strong>the</strong> efficiency of markets for technology.Under (<strong>the</strong>oretically) simple conditions, anequilibrium price will emerge where both firms– buyer and seller – will be better off afterhav<strong>in</strong>g carried out <strong>the</strong> transfer; markets work,knowledge transfer occurs. The very simplecondition is that <strong>the</strong> buyer is a more efficientuser of <strong>the</strong> technology than <strong>the</strong> seller. Thebuyer’s superior efficiency means that it canearn more from its use of <strong>the</strong> technology than<strong>the</strong> owner. Thus <strong>the</strong> buyer can still make ahigher profit than <strong>the</strong> owner would be able toearn by us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> technology itself, even if <strong>the</strong>buyer pays a somewhat costlier licence fee.S<strong>in</strong>ce TT through market transactions providesa means of obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g a sufficient reward from<strong>in</strong>novation, if <strong>the</strong> price is right, it will pay <strong>the</strong>firm to permit o<strong>the</strong>rs to use its technology.Such conditions are not likely to occur <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> case of TTs <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g very heterogeneoussystems. No equilibrium price will emerge andit is not easy for a profit-seek<strong>in</strong>g <strong>org</strong>anisationto engage <strong>in</strong> such an operation if <strong>the</strong> profitpotential is very low, or even zero.And even <strong>in</strong> a homogeneous world <strong>in</strong> which allfirms are equally technologically advanced,markets for technology as a vehicle for TT donot work that well. In a conv<strong>in</strong>c<strong>in</strong>g paper basedon recently collected evidence, Cockburn(2007) argues that it is difficult to th<strong>in</strong>k of anyo<strong>the</strong>r market that has as many failures. Thereare many obstacles to licens<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gthat:• Knowledge-based transactions are costlyand complex;• There are many “miss<strong>in</strong>g” markets forspecific technologies (difficulty <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gappropriate licensees);• Reach<strong>in</strong>g agreements regard<strong>in</strong>g price ando<strong>the</strong>r conditions is difficult; and• Operat<strong>in</strong>g managers are reluctant to selltechnologies.As a result, a large fraction of <strong>the</strong> total IP<strong>in</strong>ventory appears to be un-licensable under anycircumstances; an average of over one-third ofa firm’s total IP <strong>in</strong>ventory is considered unlikelyto be licensed, despite <strong>the</strong> firm’s will<strong>in</strong>gnessto license its technologies. These obstaclesimpose two major types of disadvantages:• “Unrealised deals,” which mean anunderutilisation of IP on <strong>the</strong> markets;and• Wrong prices for technologies, lead<strong>in</strong>g topoor outcomes.The markets for technology are <strong>the</strong>refore<strong>in</strong>efficient. Such <strong>in</strong>efficiency is even greaterwhen <strong>the</strong> market is placed upstream of <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>novation value cha<strong>in</strong> (i.e. when transactions<strong>in</strong>volve research tools, scientific <strong>in</strong>formation,etc.). Baumol’s ideal world (<strong>in</strong> which markets fortechnology work well and knowledge dissem<strong>in</strong>ateswidely and quickly through this mechanism) doesyet not exist – and perhaps never will.3.4 A Fundamental AsymmetryStronger IP protection systems create afundamental asymmetry when a proportion ofagents are “IP-users-only.” In a rich countryor region, this situation is not likely tohappen (or only marg<strong>in</strong>ally so) and a strongerIPR protection system will not generateasymmetry. Each entity is a potential IPproducer and IP consumer so that both willreceive some fur<strong>the</strong>r benefits and bearadditional costs. The only exception concerns<strong>the</strong> f<strong>in</strong>al consumers who, by def<strong>in</strong>ition,are not IP producers or holders. 11 This nonasymmetricworld is not <strong>the</strong> case, however,when <strong>the</strong> global world is considered: a largeproportion of potential patent users have nocapacity to produce IP so that <strong>the</strong> costs andbenefits of <strong>the</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> IP systemwill be unequally distributed.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development353.4.1 <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>in</strong> an asymmetric worldIn a multi-country world, <strong>the</strong> cost to one countryof <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g patent protection depends notonly on <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> deadweight loss butalso on who is do<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vent<strong>in</strong>g. If <strong>the</strong> newlyavailable patent rights for drugs <strong>in</strong> an LDC areentirely assigned to <strong>in</strong>ventors elsewhere, <strong>the</strong>loss of consumer surplus is a net cost to <strong>the</strong> LDC.All <strong>the</strong> profits accrue to foreign nationals <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>form of royalties. Thus, static costs to a country<strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g patent protection <strong>in</strong> a multi-countryworld may be higher than <strong>the</strong> standard onecountrymodel would suggest (Lanjouw, 1998).The table below summarises <strong>the</strong> static anddynamic costs and benefits result<strong>in</strong>g from astronger IPR system.Table 3. Costs and Benefits of a Stronger Patent SystemCost of strongerIPRs for country X**Benefits of strongerIPRs for country X**StaticKnowledge is bought at monopolyprice (above marg<strong>in</strong>al cost)lead<strong>in</strong>g to a loss of welfare(which can be dramatic <strong>in</strong> LDCs)*Knowledge is sold at monopolyprices and companies <strong>in</strong> X cancapture <strong>the</strong> economic rentsDynamicBarriers to access modifiabletechnologies (as base for learn<strong>in</strong>g)are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gThe pay-off structure (<strong>in</strong>centives)of <strong>the</strong> economy changes so thatentrepreneurial activities becomemore profitable.Foreign capital (R&D) is attracted* The cost of build<strong>in</strong>g a legal system is not considered here, although this can be very high <strong>in</strong> acountry where such a system does not yet exist (or is perform<strong>in</strong>g badly)** This table applies <strong>in</strong>differently to developed and develop<strong>in</strong>g countriesAs far as static cost and benefit are concerned,an LDC that has “noth<strong>in</strong>g to sell” will not benefitfrom <strong>the</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> IP system, whileit will bear <strong>the</strong> high costs of mak<strong>in</strong>g certa<strong>in</strong>essential knowledge <strong>in</strong>accessible to large fractionsof <strong>the</strong> population.As far as dynamic cost and benefit are concerned,<strong>the</strong> new system impedes learn<strong>in</strong>g by <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gbarriers to access technological componentsand modules for those who cannot afford to buytechnological licences. The benefits are clearlysignificant for catch<strong>in</strong>g-up countries that alreadyhave a class of entrepreneurs and <strong>in</strong>novativecompanies likely to respond positively (<strong>in</strong> termsof <strong>in</strong>vestments) to a stronger IP system. Theyare negligible for LDCs, however. Indeed, it isan illusion to th<strong>in</strong>k that <strong>the</strong> mere manipulationof <strong>in</strong>centives (such as creat<strong>in</strong>g an IP system)will suffice to motivate <strong>the</strong> development ofentrepreneurship and <strong>in</strong>novative activities <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>poorest countries.Us<strong>in</strong>g a general equilibrium model frameworkwith two regions (<strong>the</strong> North and South), Angeles(2005) shows that <strong>the</strong> effect of streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>gIP protection <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> South has a positive effecton <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>crease of world <strong>in</strong>novation, but thisdoes not come without costs. Higher prices forconsumers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> South are <strong>the</strong> negative side ofthis policy. The South may suffer a net welfareloss if its productivity is very low <strong>in</strong> relationto <strong>the</strong> North, which is clearly <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong>LDCs.Table 4 below presents absolute numbers ofpatent applications by residents and nonresidents<strong>in</strong> LDCs and shows that <strong>the</strong>seasymmetric relations are likely to be amplified<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> near future.


36 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesTable 4. Patent Applications by Residents and Non-residents <strong>in</strong> LDCsPatent applications by non- residentsPatent applications by residents1995 172 731996 195 116 271997 261 141 61998 449 616 701999 570 676 182000 978 409 182001 1 352 635 232002 1 753 699 6Source: WIPO, 2006Resident applications are those for which <strong>the</strong> first name applicant or assignee is a resident of <strong>the</strong> state or regionconcerned; Non-resident applications are those from applicants outside <strong>the</strong> relevant state or region.The table above not only illustrates <strong>the</strong> strongasymmetric distribution of costs and benefitsas produced <strong>in</strong> a global patent system, butit also shows very worry<strong>in</strong>g trends: while <strong>the</strong>growth of patent fil<strong>in</strong>gs by non-residents hasbeen cont<strong>in</strong>uous and significant s<strong>in</strong>ce 1995,patent fil<strong>in</strong>gs by residents show no suchtrend. No growth (even at a very low rate) isperceptible, mean<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>TRIPS</strong>on <strong>in</strong>centives and <strong>the</strong> ability of domestic andlocal entrepreneurs to patent, are negligible.As a result, <strong>the</strong> asymmetric distribution ofcosts and benefits is likely to <strong>in</strong>tensify <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>near future.Figure 2. Patent Applications <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> LDCs, Residents vs. Non-residents,1995-2002Source WIPO: 2006


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development37<strong>TRIPS</strong> works like an electric conductor. When itis set up, any failures occurr<strong>in</strong>g somewhere (<strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> rich countries) will place <strong>the</strong> whole systemat risk. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>TRIPS</strong> means that LDCsare not immune to – and <strong>in</strong> fact are extremelyexposed to – <strong>the</strong> negative excesses of <strong>the</strong> patentsystem <strong>in</strong> rich countries. In o<strong>the</strong>rs words,such excesses, which are <strong>the</strong> manifestationof a problem of pure bad governance of <strong>the</strong>system <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> rich countries, impose costs andblockages not only <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> countries responsiblefor <strong>the</strong>se excesses, but also <strong>in</strong> any country thatis signatory to <strong>the</strong> Agreement.Secondly, <strong>in</strong> an era of global <strong>in</strong>tegration,countries are not immune to repercussionsfrom <strong>the</strong> (IPR streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g) policies of o<strong>the</strong>rcountries (Hall, 2001). The streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g ofIPRs <strong>in</strong> rapidly catch<strong>in</strong>g-up economies createsa negative externality for LDCs (reduc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>centive for <strong>in</strong>novative activity <strong>in</strong> LDCs byboth attract<strong>in</strong>g R&D to move with<strong>in</strong> its bordersand rais<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> costs of follow-on <strong>in</strong>ventionelsewhere).So <strong>TRIPS</strong> is not a magic solution for promot<strong>in</strong>gTTs <strong>in</strong> LDCs. For LDCs, as far as IPRs and patentsare concerned, <strong>the</strong> correct policy orientationshould be to place more emphasis on protect<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong>se countries from <strong>the</strong> potential collateraldamage likely to be caused by IP protectionstreng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g, ra<strong>the</strong>r than us<strong>in</strong>g IP protectionas a positive market <strong>in</strong>centive to supportentrepreneurship and attract FDI. Indeed, notonly does <strong>TRIPS</strong> not solve development issues,it also creates new problems for LDCs.3.4.2 One size does not fit all and <strong>the</strong> need for flexibility <strong>in</strong> patent and copyright systemsThe fact that <strong>the</strong> costs and benefits of astronger IPR system are unequally distributed<strong>in</strong> a multi-country system and that <strong>the</strong> lessadvanced countries will bear high static anddynamic costs while not enjoy<strong>in</strong>g any benefit(at least <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> mid-term) creates a strong casefor adapt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> system to particular socioeconomiccontexts. A one-size-fits-all pr<strong>in</strong>ciplewould be suboptimal where countries’heterogeneities are concerned. As discussed<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 2002 Report of <strong>the</strong> UK Commission onIPRs, one size does not fit all. The poorestnations clearly need some flexibility as well asad hoc mechanisms to solve <strong>the</strong>ir access andknowledge production challenges.Strong arguments aga<strong>in</strong>st this one-size-doesnot-fit-allposition have been developed andare worth consider<strong>in</strong>g. The most relevantarguments aga<strong>in</strong>st this pr<strong>in</strong>ciple, however, donot deal with differences between countriesbut differences between technologies. Indeed,Jaffe (2005) argues that while it is relativelyeasy for economic <strong>the</strong>ory to demonstrate thatoptimal patent design should differ significantlyacross technological areas and <strong>in</strong>dustries andthat optimisation is achievable <strong>in</strong> a purely<strong>the</strong>oretical world, a strong case can be madefor not open<strong>in</strong>g this particular Pandora’s Box.Efforts toward some k<strong>in</strong>d of f<strong>in</strong>e-tun<strong>in</strong>g accord<strong>in</strong>gto technological heterogeneities will ultimatelyfail and are likely to weaken <strong>the</strong> patent system.Indeed, <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory identifies certa<strong>in</strong> features ofa technology that make strong or long patentsless desirable (for example, <strong>the</strong> cumulativenature of some technological knowledge, orits importance and generality). However, it isextremely difficult to identify <strong>the</strong>se features<strong>in</strong> particular technologies (this is a matter ofdegree and not clear categories). Even if <strong>in</strong>pr<strong>in</strong>ciple <strong>the</strong> applicability of patents basedon such analysis of <strong>in</strong>tr<strong>in</strong>sic technologicalpr<strong>in</strong>ciples could be restricted, it is likely that– <strong>in</strong> practice – such efforts would fail. Draftersof patent applications will always prove more<strong>in</strong>genious than writers of patent rules. Thus,prescrib<strong>in</strong>g patent protection for certa<strong>in</strong> classesof technology will simply force applications tobe written <strong>in</strong> such a way that <strong>the</strong>y appear <strong>in</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r classes. These strong arguments aga<strong>in</strong>st<strong>the</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple of one-size-does-not-fit-all do notapply, however, when heterogeneity concernsnot technologies but “socio-economic” contexts.The argument is well expressed by David <strong>in</strong> anunpublished paper, <strong>in</strong> which he states:Historical studies reveal that althoughpatents, copyrights, and legal protection


38 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economiesof trade secrets are recognisable<strong>in</strong>stitutions familiar <strong>in</strong> western societiesfor centuries, policies bear<strong>in</strong>g upon<strong>the</strong> protection accorded to <strong>in</strong>tellectualproperty and <strong>the</strong> juridical-<strong>in</strong>stitutionalarrangements used to implement <strong>the</strong>mhave been mutable th<strong>in</strong>gs, adapt<strong>in</strong>gover time and across societies to <strong>the</strong>perceived needs and advantages of<strong>in</strong>terested parties. The adaptations of<strong>the</strong> IPR systems have occurred with<strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> historical context of o<strong>the</strong>r, related,<strong>in</strong>stitutional arrangements affect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>costs and benefits of ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g specificIPRs. An implication of this observation isthat externally-dictated efforts to achievenational compliance with a uniform<strong>in</strong>ternational regime of IPR protectionare almost bound to occasion conflictand controversy. Even where it is possibleto argue that a new IPR regime couldbe constructed that would be Paretoimprov<strong>in</strong>gfor <strong>the</strong> countries <strong>in</strong>volved, <strong>the</strong>need to align domestic and <strong>in</strong>ternationallaws <strong>in</strong>troduces additional constra<strong>in</strong>tsthat tend to render such solutionsimpractical. As a result discussions on<strong>the</strong> ‘correct’ <strong>in</strong>ternational system toprotect <strong>in</strong>tellectual property are morelikely than not to degenerate <strong>in</strong>torhetorical efforts to impose <strong>in</strong>stitutionalarrangements that may well be adaptedto <strong>the</strong> national purposes and <strong>the</strong>domestic legal contexts of one country(or several similar countries) uponsocieties that are quite different <strong>in</strong>those respects.Two types of flexibility should be particularlyscrut<strong>in</strong>ised: <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternal flexibility offeredto countries by <strong>TRIPS</strong> to limit (or extend)exclusion rights, and an external flexibility,which ma<strong>in</strong>ly consists of us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> power oflegal <strong>in</strong>stitutions to reconstruct researchand <strong>in</strong>formation commons and support opensource<strong>in</strong>itiatives as a way of mitigat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>adverse effects of a highly protectionistIPR environment and promot<strong>in</strong>g low cost TTmodels <strong>in</strong> LDCs (see section 3.5, below).Fully exploit<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> scope of <strong>TRIPS</strong> flexibility<strong>in</strong> one sense or ano<strong>the</strong>r (limitations to orextension of exclusion rights) is a crucialissue. 12 But exploit<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> autonomy left opento LDCs by <strong>TRIPS</strong> not only raises questionsabout <strong>the</strong> legal rights to do so, but moreimportantly about <strong>the</strong> technical capabilitiesto use <strong>the</strong> opportunities offered by <strong>the</strong> system<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> best <strong>in</strong>terests of <strong>the</strong> knowledge ecologyof LDCs.3.4.3 Learn<strong>in</strong>g to use flexibility: a role for national patent offices<strong>TRIPS</strong> clearly offers some degree of autonomyto LDCs. However, hav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>se provisionsavailable is a different matter than be<strong>in</strong>g ableto apply <strong>the</strong>m effectively.Firstly, as already mentioned, <strong>the</strong>re arecases where LDCs formally renounce <strong>the</strong>iruse as a condition for obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g fur<strong>the</strong>r tradeadvantages through bilateral agreements.Secondly, <strong>the</strong>se mechanisms are difficultto implement and sophisticated knowledgeand skills concern<strong>in</strong>g law and <strong>in</strong>ternationalagreements are needed. This is why a <strong>TRIPS</strong>provision <strong>in</strong>volves <strong>the</strong> obligation for <strong>the</strong>developed countries to provide bilateraltechnical assistance to LDCs that requestit (see Article 67). Recent experienceshave clearly demonstrated however thatdeveloped countries provide valuable help<strong>in</strong> establish<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> appropriate measuresto streng<strong>the</strong>n IPR protection <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> countryconsidered, but do not extend that helpto <strong>the</strong> use of mechanisms like compulsorylicens<strong>in</strong>g (Kostecki, 2006). For example, <strong>the</strong>US IPR tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g coord<strong>in</strong>ation group, whichexemplifies <strong>the</strong> application of Article 67 by<strong>the</strong> US, is dom<strong>in</strong>ated by private firms andonly focuses on streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g IPR systems<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> less advanced countries. “NGOs andacademics with <strong>the</strong> knowledge and expertiseto redress <strong>the</strong> balance by highlight<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>scope for <strong>TRIPS</strong> flexibilities alongside issuesof protection and enforcement of <strong>in</strong>tellectualproperty rights are excluded from <strong>the</strong> US


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development39IPR tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g coord<strong>in</strong>ation group altoge<strong>the</strong>r”(Mat<strong>the</strong>w, 2005).There is certa<strong>in</strong>ly a role for national patentoffices to create political awareness that<strong>the</strong>se mechanisms are critically important forperform<strong>in</strong>g TTs <strong>in</strong> LDCs and, <strong>the</strong>refore, shouldnot be regarded as barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g chips <strong>in</strong> tradeagreements. Ano<strong>the</strong>r role for national patentoffices is to build and ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> legalskills essential for us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>se mechanismseffectively.3.5 Beyond IPRs: <strong>the</strong> New Knowledge Economy ParadigmAny analysis of <strong>the</strong> relationship between IPpolicies and TTs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> twenty-first centuryshould not neglect <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>novationprocess itself has changed: <strong>the</strong>re is a degreeof <strong>in</strong>novation with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> process of <strong>in</strong>novation(Ghosh and Soete, 2006).The old model of <strong>in</strong>novation was based on arelatively clear dichotomy between those with<strong>the</strong> capacities to discover new technologicalpr<strong>in</strong>ciples and those without such capacities.In such a model, TTs were dedicated to help<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> latter upgrade <strong>the</strong>ir technologies, while<strong>the</strong> former did not expect any retro-spilloversfrom TTs and <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives to promote TTswere designed accord<strong>in</strong>gly. The new model isone <strong>in</strong> which rapid collaborative processes for<strong>in</strong>cremental <strong>in</strong>novations based on free accesscreate multiple sources of new knowledge,lead<strong>in</strong>g to more efficient and faster technical<strong>in</strong>novation, with <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurial risks of<strong>in</strong>novation widely spread.The idea is to use open-source licens<strong>in</strong>g tokeep discoveries freely available to researchersand eventually manufactur<strong>in</strong>g. What seemedunfeasible a decade ago appears possible todaythanks to <strong>the</strong> greater size and variety of chemical,biological and medical databases, new softwareand more powerful computers (Maurer et al.,2004). All <strong>the</strong>se features have strongly enhanced<strong>the</strong> productivity of collaborative efforts torapidly develop knowledge and products <strong>in</strong>certa<strong>in</strong> fields.Today, technological changes make it possible toextend open-source mechanisms far beyond <strong>the</strong>field of software where this model has provedto be remarkably successful <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g a highrate of <strong>in</strong>novation and reliable products at verylow costs. This is <strong>the</strong> case of drug research,for example. The rise of <strong>in</strong> silico biology hasdramatically lowered <strong>the</strong> cost of conduct<strong>in</strong>guseful drug research. It blurs traditionaldist<strong>in</strong>ctions between drug discovery, academicdatabase production, and open-source. Commonfeatures <strong>in</strong>clude (Maurer et al., 2004):• Community-wide collaborations that producescale and network effects (<strong>the</strong> scale of<strong>the</strong> problems requires many contributors);• Loose, non-hierarchical groups work<strong>in</strong>gtoge<strong>the</strong>r to perform complex tasks andcreate specific products;• On-l<strong>in</strong>e collaboration, which dramatically<strong>in</strong>creases <strong>the</strong> productivity of collaborativeresearch; and• Unpaid volunteers who contribute to suchprojects for a host of reasons, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gidealism, learn<strong>in</strong>g new skills, ga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>greputations, and impress<strong>in</strong>g potentialemployers.Open-source discovery beyond software wouldoperate like open-source software projects.There is no reason not to expect similarlypositive results <strong>in</strong> terms of cost effectivenessand <strong>in</strong>novation performance.The ma<strong>in</strong> advantage of open-source is thatit is likely to reduce <strong>the</strong> total life cycle costrequired to get <strong>the</strong> job done. Cost effectivenessis based on <strong>the</strong> fact that such projects do notoffer f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>centives but create proper<strong>in</strong>centives for voluntary contributions. A secondreason for cost conta<strong>in</strong>ment concerns <strong>the</strong>absence of patents and above marg<strong>in</strong>al costpric<strong>in</strong>g.Innovative performance is a second advantage.It is related to <strong>the</strong> expected productivity ofsuch projects, which <strong>in</strong> turn is related to rich


40 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economiesspillovers that are created de facto <strong>in</strong> an opensourceenvironment.Last but not least, <strong>the</strong> most important enabl<strong>in</strong>gfeature of this model is access. TTs are <strong>in</strong>teractiveand reciprocal. In this paradigm, provid<strong>in</strong>gaccess to technologies and knowledge shouldnot be seen as charity or aid, but as a necessarystep to enlarge <strong>the</strong> resource base of potential<strong>in</strong>novators, i.e. a way to <strong>in</strong>crease efficiency atsystem level (Ghosh and Soete, 2006).As argued by Maurer et al. (2004), no knownscientific or economic barrier bars <strong>the</strong> way foropen-source discovery and collaborative modelsof TT.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development414. CURRENT TRENDS IN TECHNOLOGY TRANSFERThis section analyses recent data about technologydiffusion and TT toward develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries to determ<strong>in</strong>e whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> variousTT mechanisms (shown <strong>in</strong> chapter 2) are usedeffectively by countries; <strong>the</strong> extent to whichthose mechanisms play a role as an eng<strong>in</strong>e f<strong>org</strong>rowth; and if <strong>the</strong>re is any need to reconsider<strong>the</strong> general dom<strong>in</strong>ant policy that is based on<strong>the</strong> premise of <strong>the</strong> centrality of FDI and trade asTT mechanisms. The recent World Bank reportoffers a complete set of data that will be usedbelow, with a focus on technology diffusion.4.1 The World Bank FrameworkThere are two fundamental determ<strong>in</strong>ants oftechnology diffusion <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> LDCs that <strong>the</strong> WorldBank places at <strong>the</strong> centre of its framework ofanalysis. The first determ<strong>in</strong>ant <strong>in</strong>volves <strong>the</strong> threema<strong>in</strong> channels by which develop<strong>in</strong>g countries areexposed to external technologies. This <strong>in</strong>cludestrade, FDI (and licens<strong>in</strong>g that can be used as asubstitute for FDI), and highly-skilled diaspora.The o<strong>the</strong>r important determ<strong>in</strong>ant of technologydiffusion is <strong>the</strong> absorptive capacity ortechnological adaptive capacity of <strong>the</strong> country.Proper policy actions that create improvements<strong>in</strong> governance, <strong>the</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess climate, humancapital (<strong>in</strong>crease of basic technology literacy),technological capacities of firms, and access tocredit on capital markets (<strong>in</strong>novation policy)<strong>in</strong>crease this capacity.These two determ<strong>in</strong>ants are <strong>in</strong>terrelated andcreate externalities to each o<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong>rebyform<strong>in</strong>g a dynamic system with positivefeedbacks; <strong>the</strong>y generate multiple equilibriumsthrough virtuous (or vicious) circles (see e.g.Stiglitz, 1991). Such systems are well knownand well studied <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> literature of economicdevelopment.For example, <strong>the</strong> fact that a country becomesmore exposed to foreign technologies (through<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>crease of FDI) may actually <strong>in</strong>creasereturns to additional improvements of absorptivecapacity. And <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> absorptivecapacity is improv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> turn <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>the</strong>probability of spillovers be<strong>in</strong>g diffused with<strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> domestic economy. As a consequence, <strong>the</strong>overall efficiency of <strong>the</strong> economy is <strong>in</strong>creased,which positively <strong>in</strong>fluences FDI <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> country.As for any positive feedback system, <strong>the</strong>re arevirtuous circles (tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> structural form ofwhat has been just described) but also viciouscircles (Figure 3).


42 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesFigure 3. Positive Feedback Systems, Virtuous and Vicious Processes4.2 Virtuous CirclesThe basic message of <strong>the</strong> World Bank reportis that many develop<strong>in</strong>g countries – notablymiddle-<strong>in</strong>come countries – have entered avirtuous circle: <strong>the</strong> basic components of <strong>the</strong>feedback system described above are mutuallyimprov<strong>in</strong>g each o<strong>the</strong>r. The <strong>in</strong>creased exposureto foreign technology (through FDI and trade)is co-evolv<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>in</strong> dissem<strong>in</strong>ationand spillovers of <strong>the</strong>se technologies with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>domestic economy. As such, by many measures,<strong>the</strong>se countries have made outstand<strong>in</strong>g progress<strong>in</strong> technology diffusion. The ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicators ofsuch trends <strong>in</strong>volve:• The ris<strong>in</strong>g share of high tech and capitalgoods imports;• The expansion of exports of technologicalgoods;• The <strong>in</strong>crease of FDI as a percentage ofGDP, as well as <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>crease of FDI as apercentage of fixed capital formation; and• All <strong>the</strong>se trends lead<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> overall<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> exposure to external technologies<strong>in</strong>dex.Therefore, it appears that for <strong>the</strong>se countries,trade and FDI are <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> channels foraccess<strong>in</strong>g foreign technologies; TTs as a jo<strong>in</strong>tproduct work well, while absorptive capacitiesare sufficiently positive to allow spilloversfrom <strong>the</strong> technology to be transferred to<strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong> economy. Good policies andgovernance rema<strong>in</strong> of course central. This<strong>in</strong>volves keep<strong>in</strong>g FDI and trade at a high leveland cont<strong>in</strong>uously improv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> absorptivecapacity.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development43This trend is consistent with evidence on<strong>the</strong> positive relation between IPR reformand <strong>the</strong> stimulation of TTs <strong>in</strong> middle-<strong>in</strong>comecountries. The recent study by Park andLippoldt (2008) f<strong>in</strong>ds that stronger patentsystems tend to be positively associated with<strong>in</strong>ward FDI and trade, and <strong>the</strong> strength of <strong>the</strong>patent system is positively and significantlyassociated with TT (i.e. <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>flows of hightech products, like pharmaceutical goods,chemicals, aerospace, computer services,<strong>in</strong>formation, and office and telecomequipment). It is also consistent with recentempirical evidence produced by Branstetteret al. (2007), which suggests that due toIPR reform, <strong>in</strong>creased mult<strong>in</strong>ational activity<strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries is sufficiently highto offset potential decl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> imitativeactivity, suggest<strong>in</strong>g an overall enhancementof Sou<strong>the</strong>rn <strong>in</strong>dustrial development.4.3 Vicious (or Non Virtuous) Circles: <strong>the</strong> Case of LDCsUnfortunately, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of low-<strong>in</strong>comecountries, th<strong>in</strong>gs do not happen as describedabove. Empirical evidence suggests that <strong>the</strong>various channels by which countries are exposedto foreign technologies are far less powerful.FDI rema<strong>in</strong>s at a very low level (less than 1 percent of GDP) and <strong>the</strong> share of FDI <strong>in</strong> low-<strong>in</strong>comecountries capital formation is low as well. Inaddition, <strong>the</strong> ratio high tech product import/GDP is also low – LDCs rema<strong>in</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al players<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> world market for high tech goods. F<strong>in</strong>ally,hav<strong>in</strong>g a licens<strong>in</strong>g-based strategy to acquiretechnology to complement or substitute FDIis not proven to be efficient due to <strong>the</strong> lackof capabilities both <strong>in</strong> technological and legalterms and <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>efficiency of technologicalmarkets, particularly <strong>in</strong> case of transactionsbetween heterogeneous players.Least developed countries have not succeeded<strong>in</strong> improv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir absorptive capacities, whichlimits <strong>the</strong> potential for <strong>the</strong> improvement offoreign technologies to streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> domesticeconomy. How <strong>the</strong>se countries make use offoreign technologies is qualified by <strong>the</strong> WorldBank as a “passive approach and limited effortto leverage <strong>the</strong> technology imported by foreignfirms operat<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong>ir soil” (World Bank,2008).So not only has <strong>the</strong> exposure to foreign technologynot <strong>in</strong>creased that much through FDI and trade,but <strong>the</strong> extent to which <strong>the</strong>se economies havebenefited from this exposure is limited by weakcapabilities. As a result, <strong>the</strong> gap between middle<strong>in</strong>comeand low <strong>in</strong>come countries is widen<strong>in</strong>g.This is seen, for <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong> terms of <strong>the</strong> shareof capital goods <strong>in</strong> GDP.What works <strong>in</strong> middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries – TT asa jo<strong>in</strong>t product of ma<strong>in</strong> economic operations<strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g FDI and trade – does not work well <strong>in</strong>LDCs. This argument leads to one of <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>messages of this paper:In <strong>the</strong> case of LDCs, <strong>the</strong> number, scale, anddoma<strong>in</strong>s of TTs cannot be allowed to dependon general economic operations such as FDI or<strong>in</strong>frastructure construction; nei<strong>the</strong>r can <strong>the</strong>ytake <strong>the</strong> form of market transactions alone(licences). In all <strong>the</strong>se cases, <strong>the</strong> particularcircumstances and conditions prevail<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>LDCs imply a suboptimal level of TT <strong>in</strong> relationto <strong>the</strong> needs of <strong>the</strong>se countries.Therefore, augment<strong>in</strong>g FDI to emulate <strong>the</strong>successful model of some middle-<strong>in</strong>comecountries cannot be <strong>the</strong> only policy response.First, it is a long-term issue.Second, as already mentioned, TT as a jo<strong>in</strong>tproduct of FDI raises a “balanc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>centivesproblem;” a problem that is likely to be properlysolved <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of middle-<strong>in</strong>come countriesbut not <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of LDCs. Let me discuss anexample to illustrate <strong>the</strong> last po<strong>in</strong>t. Chapter 2discussed both <strong>the</strong> advantages and drawbacks ofFDI as a TT channel. The drawbacks <strong>in</strong>volve <strong>the</strong>fact that decisions concern<strong>in</strong>g most aspects ofTT rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> hands of <strong>the</strong> foreign <strong>in</strong>vestorsand as a consequence <strong>the</strong>re are doubts aboutforeign <strong>in</strong>vestors devot<strong>in</strong>g sufficient resourcesand time to <strong>the</strong> learn<strong>in</strong>g process. For example,foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors are likely to have little<strong>in</strong>centives to <strong>in</strong>itiate a shift <strong>in</strong> responsibilitiesfor technological adaptations to local suppliersor staff, preferr<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stead to delay <strong>the</strong>


44 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economiesreplacement of expatriates. This prevents <strong>the</strong>learn<strong>in</strong>g process from tak<strong>in</strong>g place. Now <strong>the</strong>sedrawbacks are clearly mitigated <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case ofcountries with stronger absorptive capacitiesand thus <strong>the</strong>se countries rightly rely on FDIto operate TTs. But as absorptive capacitiesare low, <strong>the</strong> FDI’s drawbacks are not reduced.In <strong>the</strong> example above, <strong>the</strong> cost of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gcapabilities so that at some po<strong>in</strong>t local staffcan replace expatriates can be so high that<strong>the</strong> foreign <strong>in</strong>vestor will not consider thisreplacement as an economically viable option.In <strong>the</strong> case of LDCs, TTs cannot only be a byproductor jo<strong>in</strong>t product of ano<strong>the</strong>r k<strong>in</strong>d ofeconomic operations. Incentives are likely tobe strongly imbalanced between mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>vestment operational and effective, andsucceed<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> TT and learn<strong>in</strong>g. The o<strong>the</strong>r policyresponse is to provide additional <strong>in</strong>centivesto undertake projects <strong>in</strong> which TT is <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>operation.There is <strong>the</strong>refore an economic rationalityfor specific projects <strong>in</strong> which <strong>the</strong> TT is <strong>the</strong>primary operation (an economic project <strong>in</strong>itself, not l<strong>in</strong>ked with ano<strong>the</strong>r economicoperation), but entails a very low expectedprivate profitability for <strong>the</strong> technologyown<strong>in</strong>gfirm. Such a prospect would <strong>in</strong>volveacknowledg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> existence of TT operationswith far smaller commercial returns orno commercial return at all and f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>goperational mechanisms to <strong>in</strong>centivise <strong>the</strong>sefirms to s<strong>in</strong>k costs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se operations. Sucha strategy obviously requires <strong>the</strong> provision ofadditional <strong>in</strong>centives.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development455. THE ECONOMICS OF PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS FOR TECHNOLOGYTRANSFERS BETWEEN DEVELOPED COUNTRIES AND LDCSThis study has shown that <strong>the</strong>re is an obviouseconomic rationale for specific projects<strong>in</strong> which TT is <strong>the</strong> primary operation (aneconomic project <strong>in</strong> itself not l<strong>in</strong>ked withano<strong>the</strong>r economic operation). TT as a ma<strong>in</strong>operation provides opportunities for shift<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> locus of decision to “local agents.”This would affect <strong>the</strong> modes and quality oflearn<strong>in</strong>g, technology transfer and <strong>the</strong> choiceof <strong>the</strong> area to be concentrated on. In contrastwith TT as a jo<strong>in</strong>t product, TT as a ma<strong>in</strong>operation offers an opportunity to prioritisesome doma<strong>in</strong>s.But TT as a ma<strong>in</strong> operation is costly when<strong>the</strong> recipient has weak capabilities. Thisis due to <strong>the</strong> cost of build<strong>in</strong>g capabilitiesand support<strong>in</strong>g absorption, adaptation,assimilation of subsequent improvements,and <strong>the</strong> generalisation of <strong>the</strong> technology<strong>in</strong> a system exhibit<strong>in</strong>g low absorptivecapacities.Given <strong>the</strong>se arguments, private firms that hold<strong>the</strong> technology cannot realistically be expectedto f<strong>in</strong>d sufficient market <strong>in</strong>centives to <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong> this activity at <strong>the</strong> socially desirable levelany more than governments of rich countriescan be expected to force companies to do so.Without additional <strong>in</strong>centives, TTs carried outwith LDCs would ma<strong>in</strong>ly be <strong>the</strong> result of moregeneral economic operations, such as FDI or<strong>the</strong> construction of <strong>in</strong>frastructures. In all <strong>the</strong>secases, TT is at best a jo<strong>in</strong>t product (or evenby-product), which is <strong>the</strong>refore dependent on<strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> operation.Incentivis<strong>in</strong>g foreign firms to enter suchtransactions is an opportunity for developedcountry governments to properly fulfil <strong>the</strong>irobligations as conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> Article 66.2 of <strong>TRIPS</strong>.In somewhat vague terms, Article 66.2 callsfor <strong>the</strong> provision of additional <strong>in</strong>centives fordeveloped country firms and o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>org</strong>anisationsto undertake TTs to LDCs.This section provides some recommendationson <strong>the</strong> best approach for developedcountries to fulfil <strong>the</strong>ir obligations <strong>in</strong> thisdoma<strong>in</strong>. It also discusses <strong>the</strong> centralityof “specialised agents” (PPPs) to ensureboth <strong>the</strong> effectiveness of governments’<strong>in</strong>terventions and <strong>the</strong> efficiency of <strong>the</strong> TToperation.5.1 The Economic Rationale of <strong>TRIPS</strong> Article 66.2: <strong>the</strong> Potential andLimitations of IncentivesArticle 66.2 of <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> Agreement asksdeveloped country members to provide <strong>in</strong>centivesto <strong>the</strong>ir enterprises and <strong>in</strong>stitutions forpromot<strong>in</strong>g and encourag<strong>in</strong>g transfer to LDCs.This is <strong>in</strong>deed an economically valid prescriptionas argued above. However, many obstacles andlimitations impede <strong>the</strong> ability of governmentsto <strong>in</strong>fluence firms’ decisions regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>undertak<strong>in</strong>g of TTs with LDCs. In its report, <strong>the</strong>European Community (2007) acknowledges <strong>the</strong>difficulty of putt<strong>in</strong>g Article 66.2 <strong>in</strong>to practice.Some issues that it notes are:• The private and commercial sector is clearly<strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> source of technologies, and <strong>in</strong> thiscontext, TT is often one component of amore complex project, ra<strong>the</strong>r than a standaloneactivity;• In <strong>the</strong>ir efforts to encourage and promoteTTs, governments are limited by two factors:<strong>the</strong>y do not own <strong>the</strong> vast majority of <strong>the</strong>technologies and <strong>the</strong>y cannot force <strong>the</strong>private sector to transfer its technologies;• Government <strong>in</strong>centives to undertake TTsto LDCs are only one of many factorsrelevant to companies’ decisions onwhere to direct FDI and TTs. O<strong>the</strong>r factorslike macroeconomic stability, a safelegal framework, and a well-function<strong>in</strong>ggovernment adm<strong>in</strong>istration are alsoimportant drivers;• Incentives can only take <strong>the</strong> form ofencouragement, promotion, and facilitationof <strong>the</strong> most fruitful projects.


46 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesAga<strong>in</strong>st this background, <strong>the</strong> report considersthat <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>centives are relevant andmust be activated by governments:• Promotion of projects such as FDI,subcontract<strong>in</strong>g, licens<strong>in</strong>g, franchis<strong>in</strong>g;• Improvement of access to techniques and<strong>in</strong>dustrial processes;• Support of jo<strong>in</strong>t projects;• Provision of tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> management oftechnology and production methods;• Improvement of absorptive capacities; and• Encouragement of trade <strong>in</strong> technologicalgoods.5.2 Historical Precedents: Both Incentives and Specialised <strong>Age</strong>nts <strong>in</strong> PPPsMatterThere are historical precedents show<strong>in</strong>g that<strong>the</strong> manipulation of <strong>in</strong>centives <strong>in</strong> an area oflow private profitability can profoundly change<strong>the</strong> strategic behaviours of economic agents.The reader must understand that <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>gexample does not directly concern <strong>in</strong>centivesto undertake TTs. Ra<strong>the</strong>r, it shows that it ispossible to create sufficient <strong>in</strong>centives andconta<strong>in</strong> costs <strong>in</strong> an effective way so that privatecompanies commit resources to projects <strong>in</strong>itiallycharacterised by low profitability expectations.While <strong>the</strong> usual approach had been to estimate<strong>the</strong> m<strong>in</strong>imum level of commercial profits and <strong>the</strong>nsupplement low develop<strong>in</strong>g country purchas<strong>in</strong>gpower with large market pull <strong>in</strong>centives(advanced purchase commitments), <strong>the</strong> newerapproach is to recognise <strong>the</strong> existence of R&Doperations with far smaller commercial returns(for small bus<strong>in</strong>ess) or no commercial return atall (but no loss) for large companies and to f<strong>in</strong>doperational mechanisms to <strong>in</strong>centivise <strong>the</strong>sefirms to s<strong>in</strong>k costs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se operations. But sucha strategy requires strong cost conta<strong>in</strong>mentmechanisms. As argued by Maurer et al.(2004), <strong>the</strong> failure of Western governments andpharmaceutical companies to cure develop<strong>in</strong>gcountry diseases is almost entirely about cost.It is <strong>the</strong>refore reasonable to assume that <strong>the</strong>mechanisms presented below can break <strong>the</strong>impasse and help to support R&D <strong>in</strong>vestmentsaddress<strong>in</strong>g neglected needs.The evidence is strik<strong>in</strong>g. Over <strong>the</strong> last four years,<strong>the</strong> number of neglected-disease drug projectshas <strong>in</strong>creased significantly. As Moran (2005)put it, <strong>the</strong>re were 63 neglected-disease drugprojects under way at <strong>the</strong> end of 2004, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gtwo new drugs at <strong>the</strong> registration stage andeighteen new products <strong>in</strong> cl<strong>in</strong>ical trials. Assum<strong>in</strong>gstandard attrition rates, <strong>the</strong>se projects would beexpected to deliver eight to n<strong>in</strong>e new neglecteddisease drugs with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> next five years, even ifno fur<strong>the</strong>r projects were commenced after thistime. But new projects have been launched s<strong>in</strong>ce<strong>the</strong> end of 2004, amplify<strong>in</strong>g a trend that leads todeep-seated structural change <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> economicsand <strong>org</strong>anisation of neglected disease R&D.Commitment to such R&D by for-profit companiesthat are constra<strong>in</strong>ed by shareholders’ valuesshould not exist (accord<strong>in</strong>g to economic <strong>the</strong>ory),but it does. As Galileo is said to have murmuredafter officially recant<strong>in</strong>g his statement that<strong>the</strong> Earth moves around <strong>the</strong> sun: “and yet itmoves!”.Moran (2005) argues that such an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>“non-profitable R&D” address<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> neglectedneeds of LDCs <strong>in</strong>dicates deep-seated structuralchanges. Three ma<strong>in</strong> characteristics areobservable:- Mult<strong>in</strong>ational companies work on a noncommercialbasis – that is, <strong>the</strong>y are notmotivated by commercial returns for this k<strong>in</strong>d ofproject and agree to provide <strong>the</strong> f<strong>in</strong>al productsto poor countries at not-for-profit prices. Longtermbus<strong>in</strong>ess considerations <strong>in</strong>clude reputationeffects, corporate social responsibility, ethicalconcerns, and strategic considerations, suchas <strong>the</strong> growth potential of LDC markets <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>long run. One important change that helped<strong>the</strong>se companies undertake <strong>the</strong>se strategies wasmov<strong>in</strong>g upstream to <strong>the</strong> less expensive and more


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development47<strong>in</strong>novative drug discovery stages, allow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>mto ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> costs and resource <strong>in</strong>puts at levelsmore acceptable to shareholders.- Smaller scale commercial firms do not abandon<strong>the</strong> idea of profit-mak<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>the</strong>ir projects butare motivated by far smaller commercial returnsthan large companies. They see LDC markets assufficiently attractive to warrant some positivereturns, although not at a rate that would berequired by larger firms or external <strong>in</strong>vestors.- Public-private partnerships. None of <strong>the</strong>commitments from <strong>the</strong> large MNCs and smallerbus<strong>in</strong>esses would be possible without <strong>the</strong>contribution of PPPs. In <strong>the</strong> case of largecompanies, PPPs facilitate fur<strong>the</strong>r developmentby subsidis<strong>in</strong>g cl<strong>in</strong>ical trial costs and etc. The<strong>in</strong>tervention of PPPs is critical to susta<strong>in</strong> this“no profit no loss model,” which allows largecompanies to participate <strong>in</strong> neglected diseaseresearch while still protect<strong>in</strong>g shareholder valueand manufactur<strong>in</strong>g. It also enables <strong>the</strong>m todistribute f<strong>in</strong>al products to develop<strong>in</strong>g countrypatients at no mark-up. In <strong>the</strong> case of smallerbus<strong>in</strong>esses, <strong>the</strong>se companies need substantialPPP support, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g full cost coverage andsignificant skills <strong>in</strong>put. Thus PPPs seem to be <strong>the</strong>critical <strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>in</strong>novation for new modelsof research, someth<strong>in</strong>g that seemed impossible(because it was unprofitable) some years ago.But <strong>the</strong> operational role of PPPs goes far beyondtarget<strong>in</strong>g fund<strong>in</strong>g at ad hoc R&D projects. PPPsplay a role <strong>in</strong> coord<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g and assembl<strong>in</strong>gdispersed resources that ga<strong>in</strong> value through <strong>the</strong>irassociation.The very economics of R&D <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> fields tellsus that R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments constantly generateexcess capacity. This is due to <strong>in</strong>divisibilitiesof R&D <strong>in</strong>vestments (you cannot <strong>in</strong>vest belowa certa<strong>in</strong> threshold and this applies to bothphysical and human resources); and patentraces phenomena that may lead ei<strong>the</strong>r toover<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> R&D or <strong>the</strong> proliferation ofIPRs – not all appreciated by firms <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> contextof <strong>the</strong> patent race considered.The context of excess capacity is a structuralfeature of <strong>the</strong> economic <strong>org</strong>anisation of R&Dbased on certa<strong>in</strong> characteristics, such as m<strong>in</strong>imumefficient scale, lump<strong>in</strong>ess, and <strong>in</strong>divisibility, aswell as <strong>in</strong>centive structures, like patent races.While some of <strong>the</strong>se resources can be sold on asecond-hand market, <strong>the</strong> role of PPPs is to createa feasibility space for social shar<strong>in</strong>g ra<strong>the</strong>r thanrequir<strong>in</strong>g a model of second best pric<strong>in</strong>g, andreallocate <strong>the</strong>se resources efficiently (i.e. tosocially useful projects). While <strong>in</strong>divisibilities,over<strong>in</strong>vestment, and <strong>the</strong> generation of profusionof IP (through patent races) generate challengesfor efficient pric<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>the</strong>y also create conditions<strong>in</strong> which new <strong>in</strong>stitutional mach<strong>in</strong>ery is likely toprovide a more efficient framework to supplyand exchange those goods than would <strong>the</strong> pricesystem.5.3 Public-Private Partnerships for <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>As po<strong>in</strong>ted earlier <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> paper, <strong>the</strong> complexityand difficulties of TT operations as supported and<strong>in</strong>centivised by governments of rich countriesmake it necessary to use “specialised agents”that have accumulated experiences <strong>in</strong> TT’soperations. 14 The essence of a public-privatepartnership – to put this <strong>in</strong>stitutional mechanism<strong>in</strong> contrast with <strong>the</strong> more usual “public fund<strong>in</strong>g ofprivate <strong>in</strong>itiative” k<strong>in</strong>d of arrangement – resides<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>volvement of a third party, which isspecialised <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g public donors, privatefirms, and local entrepreneurial activities toensure <strong>the</strong> effectiveness of <strong>the</strong> operation.The third party is a not-for-profit <strong>org</strong>anisationwhose objective is to efficiently managepublic or philanthropic fund<strong>in</strong>g. As a generalstatement, <strong>the</strong> PPPs will establish <strong>the</strong> l<strong>in</strong>k andmake it operational and effective between <strong>the</strong>public donor, a private company that holds <strong>the</strong>technology, and local demand.


48 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economies5.3.1 The essence of a PPP: <strong>the</strong> functional role of a third partyAs a specialised entity, <strong>the</strong> PPP will compensatefor <strong>the</strong> critical deficit of <strong>in</strong>stitutional mechanismsboth <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> LDC and <strong>the</strong> developedcountry, which are needed to address problemsaris<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>the</strong> management of a TT as a ma<strong>in</strong>operation (see Figure 4). The PPP will:• Make sure that <strong>the</strong> whole process is“demand pull” (i.e. an area or field of TTthat clearly matches a local entrepreneurialneed) and create <strong>the</strong> proper <strong>in</strong>centivestructure for <strong>the</strong> local entrepreneurs toengage resources <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> project;• Target <strong>the</strong> appropriate partner (technologyholder) and generate <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive to<strong>in</strong>volve it <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> transaction;• Create <strong>the</strong> proper conditions to conta<strong>in</strong>costs – a crucial condition for <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> anticipated private profitability ofTTs;• Generate <strong>the</strong> proper <strong>org</strong>anisational forms(<strong>in</strong>ternal and external, i.e. platforms) toensure <strong>the</strong> TT will successfully meet <strong>the</strong>different phases (absorption, adaptation,assimilation of subsequent improvements,generalisation), s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong>re is no “superior”economic operation that will provide<strong>the</strong> <strong>org</strong>anisational structure, such aswhen <strong>the</strong> TT is a jo<strong>in</strong>t product of a direct<strong>in</strong>vestment;• Supervise <strong>the</strong> whole process so that <strong>the</strong>various phases of <strong>the</strong> TT are successfullymanaged;• Create mutual contractual obligations sothat no party can leave <strong>the</strong> project beforeits completion; and• Last but not least, manage <strong>the</strong> IPR side.As already argued (chapter 2, 2.5) <strong>the</strong> locusof decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g with regard to undertak<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> TT <strong>in</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong> field and under specificconditions is also an important variable whenTT is <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> operation. In circumstanceswhere TT is <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> operation, <strong>the</strong> locus ofdecision-mak<strong>in</strong>g should not be kept <strong>in</strong> foreignassistance bodies but transferred to localgovernment <strong>in</strong>itiatives and entrepreneurs. PPPswill be central <strong>in</strong> manag<strong>in</strong>g such a shift.Figure 4. Functions and Role of a PPP as TT Operator


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development495.3.2 Supply side: “right” technology holders?Are <strong>the</strong>re any “model of firms” <strong>in</strong> developedcountries that might be more capable than o<strong>the</strong>rsto enter such operations of TT toward LDCs, given<strong>the</strong> constra<strong>in</strong>ts mentioned above (disarticulatedsystem, weak capabilities, low affordability of<strong>the</strong> potential clients”)? If <strong>the</strong> answer is yes, onerole of government policy is to identify and enrolthose firms <strong>in</strong>to TT’s projects.Arora et al. (2001) developed <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g casestudies of specialised technology suppliers <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> chemical <strong>in</strong>dustry. They studied how <strong>the</strong>development of specialised upstream technologysuppliers <strong>in</strong> developed countries improvestechnology access and lowers <strong>in</strong>vestment costsfor downstream firms <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries.Test<strong>in</strong>g this idea <strong>the</strong>y showed that <strong>in</strong>vestments<strong>in</strong> chemical plants are greater <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries where <strong>the</strong> number of technologysuppliers that operate <strong>in</strong> developed countriesis greater. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> authors, whatmatters is <strong>the</strong>refore <strong>the</strong> vertical <strong>org</strong>anisationof <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> developed world. Thatis, <strong>in</strong>vestment is tak<strong>in</strong>g place earlier and morerapidly than if develop<strong>in</strong>g countries had to relysolely upon chemical producers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> developedworld to transfer <strong>the</strong> technology. The mechanismis quite simple: specialised suppliers developtechnological capabilities that are <strong>the</strong>n sold todownstream firms. Because <strong>the</strong> expertise and<strong>the</strong> technologies developed are process (and notlocation) specific, <strong>the</strong>y can be made available todownstream firms <strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r countries. Moreover,competition between suppliers implies that<strong>the</strong> expertise and <strong>the</strong> technology will be madeavailable to prices close to <strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al costof transfer. The economic logic of this story is<strong>the</strong>refore that <strong>the</strong> fixed cost of develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>technology is paid by <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustries or countriesthat emerge earlier, while <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustries orcountries that come later pay only <strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>alcost.As a consequence of a certa<strong>in</strong> stage of verticaldis<strong>in</strong>tegration of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry, <strong>the</strong> presence of<strong>in</strong>dependent suppliers that do not produce <strong>the</strong>downstream product is important. Downstreamproducers (chemical firms) are less likely to selltechnology to potential competitors (located <strong>in</strong>less developed economies). Thus, specialisationand division of labour can have a benefit for<strong>in</strong>dustrial growth – that is, <strong>the</strong> ability and <strong>in</strong>terestof <strong>in</strong>dependent suppliers to operate TTs whilenot underm<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir competitive position.Given this result, governments should notrandomly screen <strong>the</strong> entire firm’s pool of richcountries to identify potentially reliable partnersable and will<strong>in</strong>g to take part <strong>in</strong> TT’s operations.Ra<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>the</strong> critical task of identify<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> right firms that are naturally and logicallyadapted to this k<strong>in</strong>d of operation.5.3.3 Prioritis<strong>in</strong>gDoma<strong>in</strong>s to be prioritised by governments<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir effort to comply with Article 66.2obligations <strong>in</strong>volve two basic criteria:1. Doma<strong>in</strong>s where additional <strong>in</strong>centivesare actually needed. There are doma<strong>in</strong>swhere market <strong>in</strong>centives are sufficientlyhigh for motivat<strong>in</strong>g foreign firms tocommit resources; and2. Doma<strong>in</strong>s where <strong>the</strong>re is clear demandfor technology from local entrepreneurs,who <strong>the</strong>n are <strong>in</strong>centivised to develop<strong>in</strong>novation projects to suit local needsand markets and are likely to generatespillovers more easily captured by <strong>the</strong> localeconomy (more easily than those spilloversgenerated through FDI and <strong>the</strong> productionof knowledge for global markets).To summarise, prioritisation undertaken as aresponse to <strong>the</strong> 66.2 provision should emphasisedoma<strong>in</strong>s that correspond to a certa<strong>in</strong> model of<strong>in</strong>novation, which is central to LDCs: locallyoriented<strong>in</strong>novations address<strong>in</strong>g local needsthrough local entrepreneurial activities thatallow <strong>the</strong> country to develop absorptivecapacities. These doma<strong>in</strong>s are important for


50 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economiesgrowth because <strong>the</strong> spillovers generated <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> course of such projects are likely to becaptured by <strong>the</strong> local economy. Moreover,<strong>the</strong>se doma<strong>in</strong>s need additional <strong>in</strong>centives so<strong>the</strong> donor’s <strong>in</strong>tervention will be effective andrespond fully to <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> provision. This isnot necessarily <strong>the</strong> case for export-orientedsectors <strong>in</strong> which market <strong>in</strong>centives alone aresufficiently strong to motivate firms <strong>in</strong> richcountries to operate TTs.The o<strong>the</strong>r doma<strong>in</strong>s – for <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>the</strong> exportgoods-oriented manufactur<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>gsectors – are also important but <strong>the</strong>y will, <strong>in</strong>any case, be served through TTs operat<strong>in</strong>g as ajo<strong>in</strong>t product of FDI. TTs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se doma<strong>in</strong>s donot require additional <strong>in</strong>centives provided by<strong>the</strong> government. They are <strong>the</strong> natural resultof rationale and profit-maximis<strong>in</strong>g strategiesof foreign firms.Hav<strong>in</strong>g made <strong>the</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t that local <strong>in</strong>novationsare socially useful and are likely to generate avirtuous process of diffusion and <strong>in</strong>formationspillovers with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> domestic economy doesnot mean that market <strong>in</strong>centives would beenough to <strong>in</strong>itiate local entrepreneurial<strong>in</strong>itiative towards <strong>the</strong>se local needs.The figure below illustrates why <strong>the</strong> issueof <strong>in</strong>centives needs to be addressed <strong>in</strong> thisparticular case. DG denotes <strong>the</strong> demand fromadvanced countries (<strong>the</strong> global demand); DL is<strong>the</strong> local demand; and AC is <strong>the</strong> average costcurve fac<strong>in</strong>g local <strong>in</strong>novators (with a shapedriven by a fixed cost like R&D).Figure 5. Global and Local Demand and <strong>the</strong> Need for Special Incentivesfor Local EntrepreneursPACDGD LSource: Trajtenberg, 2008QThe DL slope shows buyers for whom quantitiespurchased are extremely price sensitive,as compared with buyers whose demandsare more <strong>in</strong>elastic (DG). In this case, localentrepreneurs – if <strong>the</strong>y have <strong>the</strong> capacity –will likely develop an <strong>in</strong>novation to serve <strong>the</strong>global demand because do<strong>in</strong>g so would result<strong>in</strong> positive profits, whereas, as it stands,serv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> local market would not cover <strong>the</strong>fixed cost.A small R&D subsidy may tip <strong>the</strong> balance andmake it profitable to <strong>in</strong>novate for <strong>the</strong> localmarket, and <strong>the</strong> local surplus generated maybe significantly larger than <strong>the</strong> subsidy. Thesocial ga<strong>in</strong>s of serv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> local market with


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development51regard to consumer surplus may be significant,as is likely to be <strong>the</strong> case <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> area of medicalcare. Moreover, local spillovers may, <strong>in</strong> somecases, be more significant and widespread if<strong>in</strong>novat<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>the</strong> local market, if only becauseof <strong>the</strong> demonstration effects.This case shows clearly that even if <strong>the</strong>technology is transferred for free – due to<strong>the</strong> additional <strong>in</strong>centives received by <strong>the</strong>technology holder – it might not be enough to<strong>in</strong>centivise local entrepreneurial activities.Subsidies allocated to <strong>the</strong> local side might beneeded to operate <strong>the</strong> various tasks that arenecessary (absorption, adaptation, assimilationof improvements) to make <strong>the</strong> TT a successfuloperation. Invest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>novation orientedtowards local needs may, <strong>the</strong>refore, requireadditional support from <strong>the</strong> government to <strong>the</strong>local entrepreneurial activities.5.3.4 Special IPRs for public-private partnershipsThere is a grow<strong>in</strong>g awareness of <strong>the</strong> potentialrole of PPPs to address <strong>the</strong> issues of accessto and management of IPRs <strong>in</strong> cases of TTs(see for <strong>in</strong>stance de Boer, 2008, about sucha role <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> area of environmentally-soundtechnology transfers).A first issue to be addressed is related to<strong>the</strong> fact that most local entrepreneursand research <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries lack even m<strong>in</strong>imal capacity <strong>in</strong>IPR management and negotiations. The PPPshould, <strong>the</strong>refore, contribute to clarify<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>stitutional roles, identify<strong>in</strong>g proprietarytechnologies, negotiat<strong>in</strong>g ownerships of IPfrom <strong>the</strong> TT, and guid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> management ofIPRs.A second issue, well addressed by Byerleeand Fischer (2002), is <strong>the</strong> contribution of<strong>the</strong> high transaction costs of patent searchesto <strong>the</strong> market failure <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternationaltransfer of proprietary technology. The PPPshould <strong>the</strong>re-fore assume <strong>the</strong> role of reduc<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> cost to develop<strong>in</strong>g countries of patentsearches and offer a “one-stop” brokerageservice for buy<strong>in</strong>g and sell<strong>in</strong>g IP.F<strong>in</strong>ally, as argued by Karap<strong>in</strong>ar and Temmerman(2007), IP-related accessibility issues could beresolved on a purely contractual or free willbasis. However, it is likely that PPPs simply basedon contractual arrangements do not reduce<strong>the</strong> risk of disagreements between partnerson commercialisation and royalty shar<strong>in</strong>g.Moreover <strong>the</strong> same authors observe that deal<strong>in</strong>gwith complex licens<strong>in</strong>g and contractual issues<strong>in</strong> each PPP results <strong>in</strong> high transaction costs(ibid.). It is important for PPPs to create a spacefor technology transferr<strong>in</strong>g at low transactioncosts. There is thus a need for devis<strong>in</strong>g a specialIP-regime tailored for PPPs that could providea more effective environment ensur<strong>in</strong>g both<strong>in</strong>centives for technology holders to be partof <strong>the</strong> transaction and easier access for localentrepreneurs.Depend<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> capacity and capability levelof <strong>the</strong> recipient country, <strong>the</strong> PPP should ei<strong>the</strong>rfocus on negotiat<strong>in</strong>g commercial licens<strong>in</strong>gagreements directly with private companies foraccess<strong>in</strong>g tools and technologies for commercialand emerg<strong>in</strong>g markets, or barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g for accessto products under royalty-free license (Byerleeand Fischer, 2002).5.4 Effectiveness Conditions: Appropriate Donor AssistanceThe use of public money to undertake TT (<strong>in</strong>order to create more <strong>in</strong>centives for <strong>the</strong> privatepartner) will be considered as efficient not onlybecause <strong>the</strong> TT meets some measure of successat <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> day (enhanc<strong>in</strong>g efficiency andgrowth <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> host country) but also because <strong>the</strong>operation would not have been possible withoutthis money. This section discusses <strong>the</strong> lattercondition, which is obvious but harder for anypublic agency to control and meet.


52 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economies5.4.1 The basic modelFigure 6 below shows when and why public<strong>in</strong>centives have to be provided to get <strong>the</strong> privatesector to carry out more TTs toward LDCs. Thisfigure can help us evaluate <strong>the</strong> effectiveness ofsubsidis<strong>in</strong>g TT. The figure shows <strong>the</strong> expectedreturns on TT <strong>in</strong> two dimensions, social andprivate (private for <strong>the</strong> firm which masters <strong>the</strong>technology). The expected total returns on aTT project are <strong>the</strong> sum of <strong>the</strong> expected socialand private returns.Government support has several possibleoutcomes. In some cases, government supportgoes to <strong>in</strong>fra-marg<strong>in</strong>al projects, which arehigh return projects that would have beenundertaken anyway (projects <strong>in</strong> Area C). In this<strong>in</strong>stance, government support is just a transferof payment. In our example, a TT aimed atimprov<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g of a good fac<strong>in</strong>gdeteriorat<strong>in</strong>g terms of trade is a case <strong>in</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t.There is no need for fur<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>centives for acompany <strong>in</strong> a developed country to transfertechnologies <strong>in</strong> such doma<strong>in</strong>s.Some of <strong>the</strong> money may go to marg<strong>in</strong>alprojects, such as projects <strong>in</strong> Areas A and B,which firms will not undertake on <strong>the</strong>ir own.If <strong>the</strong> government cannot really estimate <strong>the</strong>potential social return on <strong>the</strong>se projects, <strong>the</strong>subsidy causes firms to undertake some TTprojects that are (at <strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>) unproductiveprojects (<strong>in</strong> Area A), and also some projectsthat (at <strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>) have a total return <strong>in</strong>excess of <strong>the</strong> opportunity cost of capital thatwould not o<strong>the</strong>rwise have been undertaken(Area B).Figure 6. Projects Targeted by an Optimal Government-IndustryTT ProgrammeSource: Stiglitz and Wallsten, 1999If <strong>the</strong> government is effective <strong>in</strong> identify<strong>in</strong>gprojects with social returns not captured by<strong>the</strong> private sector (<strong>in</strong> Area B), <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> supportunambiguously <strong>in</strong>creases economic efficiency.TTs of course have to be operated <strong>in</strong> manydoma<strong>in</strong>s, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g export-oriented <strong>in</strong>dustry.But, <strong>the</strong>y must be particularly supported <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> doma<strong>in</strong>s correspond<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> model of<strong>in</strong>novation, which, as identified above, areentrepreneurial activities deal<strong>in</strong>g with needson local markets that are likely to generatedomestic spillovers. Two reasons have beengiven:


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development531. These doma<strong>in</strong>s are potentially verysignificant for growth because of <strong>the</strong>spillovers that are likely to be captured by<strong>the</strong> local economy;2. These doma<strong>in</strong>s need additional <strong>in</strong>centivesso that <strong>the</strong> donor’s <strong>in</strong>tervention will beeffective and respond fully to <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong>provision, which is not necessarily <strong>the</strong> caseof export-oriented sectors <strong>in</strong> which market<strong>in</strong>centives are only sufficiently strong tomotivate <strong>the</strong> firms of <strong>the</strong> rich countries tooperate TTs.5.4.2 Implementation issuesStiglitz and Wallsten (1999) argue that <strong>the</strong>better a government is at fund<strong>in</strong>g projects<strong>in</strong> Area B (projects with relatively high socialbenefits and low private returns), <strong>the</strong> moreeffective TT programmes will be. However,<strong>the</strong>se authors also argue that it is unclearhow this goal can best be accomplished.Most of <strong>the</strong>se programmes require <strong>in</strong>dustryto propose projects and <strong>the</strong> government todecide whe<strong>the</strong>r to subsidise <strong>the</strong>m. Often,government subsidies are less expensive thancapital from o<strong>the</strong>r sources, mean<strong>in</strong>g that firmsmay be tempted to look to government beforelook<strong>in</strong>g to o<strong>the</strong>r sources for f<strong>in</strong>ancial support.In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong>re is no reason to believethat firms will provide TT projects only <strong>in</strong>Area B. Firms may be tempted to first proposeprojects that fall with<strong>in</strong> Area C which, be<strong>in</strong>gsubsidised, will be privately super-profitable.It is up to <strong>the</strong> government to determ<strong>in</strong>e whichof <strong>the</strong>se research projects would benefit LDCsbut would not be privately profitable withouta subsidy. This means that government shouldnot simply fund <strong>the</strong> best proposals it receives.Instead, it should fund <strong>the</strong> best amongthose that could not be funded elsewhere.In o<strong>the</strong>r words, programme managers whomake fund<strong>in</strong>g decisions must reject not onlyprojects of dubious technical merit, but alsotechnologically-sound proposals that are verylikely to yield commercial successes and could<strong>the</strong>refore be funded elsewhere. In practice, itis difficult to follow such allocation pr<strong>in</strong>ciplesand <strong>the</strong> next section details that many projectsreported as a response of developed countriesto <strong>the</strong> 66.2 provision should not be subsidisedby government s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong>y clearly fall with<strong>in</strong>Area C.5.5 Draw<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>TRIPS</strong> Council Country Reports under Article 66.2The <strong>TRIPS</strong> Council at <strong>the</strong> WTO decided <strong>in</strong> 2002that developed countries should submit reportsabout <strong>the</strong>ir policy of <strong>in</strong>centives and regulatorymeasures that <strong>the</strong>y are implement<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>order to support and promote TTs from <strong>the</strong>bus<strong>in</strong>ess sector to LDCs. It was specified that<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation provided should show that <strong>the</strong>particular <strong>in</strong>centive regimes are not simply partof <strong>the</strong> general overseas development assistance(ODA) that benefits all develop<strong>in</strong>g countries butspecifically address <strong>the</strong> LDCs’ target to promoteTT. It was also requested that developedcountries should provide detailed reports on<strong>the</strong> practical function<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong>se <strong>in</strong>centivesand update <strong>the</strong> Council regularly regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>results of <strong>the</strong>se policies.At <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> Council of 2007, however, <strong>the</strong>Bangladesh representative, while appreciat<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> fact that several countries “did <strong>the</strong> job”and regularly update <strong>the</strong> Council concern<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong>ir activities <strong>in</strong> this area, compla<strong>in</strong>ed about<strong>the</strong> lack of <strong>in</strong>formation on how <strong>the</strong> technicalassistance featured <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se reports hadactually led to TTs and how <strong>the</strong> private sector isrespond<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong>se <strong>in</strong>centives (June 5, 2007).In general, LDCs expressed frustration about <strong>the</strong>fact that rich countries are not really fulfill<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong>ir obligations <strong>in</strong> relation to Article 66.2. 15There are roughly four ma<strong>in</strong> doma<strong>in</strong>s where<strong>in</strong>centives of some k<strong>in</strong>d are provided to encourageTTs with LDCs:• Doma<strong>in</strong> 1: TT to improve <strong>the</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>gand process<strong>in</strong>g of export goods (cacao,coffee, teas) that are fac<strong>in</strong>g deteriorat<strong>in</strong>gterms of trade;• Doma<strong>in</strong> 2: TT to meet vital needs (drugs andvacc<strong>in</strong>es). This is of course an importantmission but relates less to TT than to R&D


54 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economiescarried out <strong>in</strong> developed countries, <strong>the</strong>results of which are <strong>the</strong>n distributed <strong>in</strong>LDCs for passive consumption;• Doma<strong>in</strong> 3: TT to build <strong>in</strong>frastructures. It isnot clear however whe<strong>the</strong>r firms contract<strong>in</strong>gwith governments to build an <strong>in</strong>frastructurehave strong TT duties; and• Doma<strong>in</strong> 4: TT <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> area of simple andtraditional capital goods and servicesoriented toward local entrepreneurialactivities <strong>in</strong> relation to domestic needs.Study<strong>in</strong>g country reports leads to <strong>the</strong> conclusionthat governments report a high concentration ofprojects <strong>in</strong> Doma<strong>in</strong> 1, moderate concentration<strong>in</strong> Doma<strong>in</strong>s 2 and 3, and low concentration <strong>in</strong>Doma<strong>in</strong> 4 (see Table 5 below as an example).This does not represent a very strong result<strong>in</strong> terms of government effectiveness s<strong>in</strong>ceDoma<strong>in</strong> 1 clearly corresponds to Area C<strong>in</strong> Figure 6, i.e. projects that would havebeen undertaken anyway. Doma<strong>in</strong> 2 clearlycorresponds to Area B <strong>in</strong> Figure 6, i.e. projectsthat need to be subsidised but are not pure TTprojects. Doma<strong>in</strong> 4 also corresponds to Area Band does <strong>in</strong>volve true TT operations but veryfew projects are actually undertaken.Some government <strong>in</strong>terventions entail <strong>the</strong>risk of super-<strong>in</strong>efficiency. This is <strong>the</strong> caseof subsidies to projects <strong>in</strong> Doma<strong>in</strong> 1. Theseprojects do not need fur<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>centives s<strong>in</strong>ce<strong>the</strong> positive effects of efficiency improvementswill be primarily beneficial to firms fromdeveloped countries import<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>se goods.As already expla<strong>in</strong>ed (chapter 4), s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong>segoods are characterised by deteriorat<strong>in</strong>g termsof trade, successful TTs are likely to worsen <strong>the</strong>economic situation of <strong>the</strong> considered sector <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> LDCs. In help<strong>in</strong>g such projects, governmentsare <strong>the</strong>refore be<strong>in</strong>g super-<strong>in</strong>efficient. Theyare help<strong>in</strong>g projects that would be carried outanyway and <strong>the</strong>se projects are not likely toimprove <strong>the</strong> economic situation of <strong>the</strong> poorestcountries.To conclude, it appears that <strong>the</strong> locus ofdecision-mak<strong>in</strong>g concern<strong>in</strong>g areas and doma<strong>in</strong>sfor TTs are kept <strong>in</strong> foreign assistance bodies,lead<strong>in</strong>g to suboptimal decisions. For example,many projects are actually serv<strong>in</strong>g tradepolicy needs ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>in</strong>novation policy. Inaddition, governments of developed countriesare not very effective <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir allocationdecisions. Many subsidised projects do not<strong>in</strong> fact require fur<strong>the</strong>r support to be carriedout. And f<strong>in</strong>ally, country reports should bemore transparent and <strong>in</strong>formative regard<strong>in</strong>gwhich doma<strong>in</strong>s are supported and helpedthrough TTs and <strong>the</strong> provision of <strong>in</strong>centives.The development of a standard typology ofareas for TTs that developed countries woulduse systematically to report on <strong>the</strong>ir activitiescould go a long way towards mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>sereports more <strong>in</strong>formative (see table below).


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development55Table 5. Mapp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>s: An Example Based On CountryReports to <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> Council under Article 66.2TT doma<strong>in</strong>sInstitutionalsourcesPrivateExportorientedgoodsDeteriorat<strong>in</strong>gterms of tradeVital needs:education,healthInfrastructureSimple capital goodsand services to serveentrepreneurialactivitiesOrganic cotton(Mali)Cashew nuts,fruits, cotton(Mozambique)Coffee, cashewnuts (Tanzania)Mango (Burk<strong>in</strong>a)Coffee (Zambia)Efficiency <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>brick sector (Nepal)PublicProductionReform ofhealth system(Tanzania)Malaria research(Tanzania)Watermanagement(Burk<strong>in</strong>a)PublicProcurementBridge and roadbuild<strong>in</strong>g(Tanzania)Source: This table is based on a country report submitted to <strong>the</strong> Council for <strong>TRIPS</strong>, WTO, 2006.The recent Policy Brief by S. Moon (2008), thatsystematically analyses <strong>the</strong> reports submitted bycountries to <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> Council, provides similarconclusions. It concludes that <strong>the</strong> evidenceproduced by her study “does not pa<strong>in</strong>t a rosypicture of compliance with Article 66.2.” Moonpo<strong>in</strong>ts to <strong>the</strong> lack of def<strong>in</strong>ition of <strong>the</strong> basicterms (technology transfer, developed country),<strong>the</strong> absence of data and <strong>in</strong>dicators requirementto measure efforts, and <strong>the</strong> vagueness of <strong>the</strong>description of <strong>the</strong> general obligations. A majorityof projects listed by countries as part of <strong>the</strong>irefforts to comply with 66.2 just miss <strong>the</strong> target: asignificant proportion of programmes actually donot encourage TT while a majority of <strong>the</strong>m do notspecifically target LDCs. Given this poor activitiesreport<strong>in</strong>g, which creates a very opaque situationand makes it difficult to evaluate efforts andobserve progress (or stagnation) over time andbetween countries, short-term recommendationsare obviously very practical, <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>standardisation of <strong>the</strong> report<strong>in</strong>g procedure, <strong>the</strong>def<strong>in</strong>ition of common format and categories, <strong>the</strong>emphasis on data collection, and presentation.However <strong>the</strong>se needed efforts should not hide <strong>the</strong>long-term objective, which has been articulatedand clarified <strong>in</strong> this paper: mak<strong>in</strong>g TT an effectivetool for <strong>in</strong>novation and growth <strong>in</strong> LDCs.


56 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesConclusion<strong>Technology</strong> transfer is a difficult and complexprocess, particularly for LDCs which suffer froma limited exposure to foreign technologies and aweak absorptive capacity. These countries cannotonly rely on FDI and trade to access foreigntechnologies and TTs which are likely to spillover<strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> domestic economy as a result.Effective TTs to LDCs call for new types of PPPswith <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>volvement of a third party, which isspecialised <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g public donors, private firms,and local entrepreneurial activities to ensure <strong>the</strong>effectiveness of <strong>the</strong> TT operation. The PPP willwork to ensure that <strong>the</strong> locus of decision-mak<strong>in</strong>gon TT is shifted to local actors and authorities. ThePPP would also contribute to clarify<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutionalroles, identify<strong>in</strong>g proprietary technologies andguid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> management of IPRs.Practical means to make <strong>the</strong> implementation of<strong>TRIPS</strong> Article 66.2 more effective should <strong>in</strong>cludedeveloped countries provid<strong>in</strong>g more effective<strong>in</strong>centives, by offer<strong>in</strong>g assistance to projectsthat are socially beneficial but not profitablefor <strong>the</strong> firms that own and could transfer <strong>the</strong>technology.In this connection, developed countries shouldalso ensure that conditions for efficient TToperations <strong>in</strong>volve <strong>the</strong> choice of relevant partnerson supply and demand sides, <strong>the</strong> selection of<strong>the</strong> right areas for focus (related to a clearlyexpressed local demand for technology) and <strong>the</strong>creation of <strong>org</strong>anisational forms that will favour<strong>the</strong> consolidation of <strong>the</strong> transfer (absorption,adaptation and subsequent spillover), as well as<strong>the</strong> related entrepreneurial dynamic.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development57ENDNOTES1 See L<strong>in</strong>su Kim (2003), <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> and Intellectual Property Rights: Lessons fromKorea’s Experience, ICTSD Issue Paper No. 2; Sanjaya Lall, with <strong>the</strong> collaboration of ManuelAlbaladejo (2003), Indicators of <strong>the</strong> Relative Importance of IPRs <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries,ICTSD Issue Paper No.3; UNCTAD-ICTSD Policy Discussion Paper, Intellectual Property Rights:Implications for Development (2003); John Barton (2004), Nutrition and <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>Policies, ICTSD Issue Paper No. 6; Keith Maskus (2004), Encourag<strong>in</strong>g International <strong>Technology</strong><strong>Transfer</strong>, UNCTAD-ICTSD Issue Paper No.7; UNCTAD-ICTSD Resource Book on <strong>TRIPS</strong> andDevelopment, Cambridge University Press; John Barton (2007), New Trends <strong>in</strong> <strong>Technology</strong><strong>Transfer</strong>: Implications for National and International Policy, ICTSD Issue Paper No. 18.2 These concepts are def<strong>in</strong>ed as <strong>the</strong>y are employed <strong>in</strong> account<strong>in</strong>g: jo<strong>in</strong>t products are twoproducts that are simultaneously yielded from one shared cost and <strong>the</strong>y have comparably high(sales) value. By-products for <strong>the</strong>ir part are produced along with a ma<strong>in</strong> product. The latterconstitutes <strong>the</strong> major portion of <strong>the</strong> total (sales) value. By-products have a considerably lower(sales) value than <strong>the</strong>se ma<strong>in</strong> products. We can apply <strong>the</strong>se concepts to TTs, substitut<strong>in</strong>g“perceived value to technology holders” for “sales value.”3 The discussion <strong>in</strong> this section draws heavily on my scholarly exchange and many discussionswith M.Trajtenberg whose syn<strong>the</strong>tic view on <strong>the</strong>se issues for LDCs can be found <strong>in</strong> Trajtenberg(2007).4 This section draws on <strong>the</strong> literature that focuses on TT channels, <strong>the</strong>ir respective advantagesand shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs. It refers especially to Maskus, 2004, Barton, 2007, and <strong>the</strong> World Bank,2008.5 This is for <strong>in</strong>stance a fundamental weakness of <strong>the</strong> provisions made under Article 66.2 of <strong>the</strong><strong>TRIPS</strong>, which are <strong>in</strong>tended to encourage firms <strong>in</strong> developed countries to transfer technologiestowards LDCs. Noth<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this article specifies how (and where) decisions should be made.These provisions are obviously not provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> anticipated results.6 The transitional period expired <strong>in</strong> this case on 1 January 2005.7 It is also useful to recall that countries like Switzerland or Japan did <strong>the</strong> same th<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>19th and early 20th centuries to build <strong>the</strong>ir own competitive <strong>in</strong>dustries.8 Reverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g of software is acceptable with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> framework but legal conditionsare implemented differently at <strong>the</strong> national level, mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> legal framework for reverseeng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g difficult to understand and to cope with (see UNCTAD-ICTSD, 2005).9 These <strong>in</strong>dustries share <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g characteristics that obviously make patents a quiteeffective <strong>in</strong>centive mechanism: high R&D cost, reverse eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g, and o<strong>the</strong>r means of<strong>in</strong>novation reproduction allow competitors for rapid and <strong>in</strong>expensive imitations, and lowcosts of manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> f<strong>in</strong>al product.10 The author warmly thanks K.Karachalios from <strong>the</strong> EPO for call<strong>in</strong>g attention to this argumentand provid<strong>in</strong>g some very <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g documentation on <strong>the</strong> Ethiopian case.11 Open-source and community-based user <strong>in</strong>novation projects can be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as a mechanismto mitigate <strong>the</strong> formation of asymmetry between f<strong>in</strong>al user and commercial producer dur<strong>in</strong>g aperiod of IP protection streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g.12 See Roffe et al. (2007) for an overview of <strong>the</strong> various types of flexibility <strong>in</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong>.


58 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced Economies13 PPPs are not-for-profit <strong>org</strong>anisations that support and coord<strong>in</strong>ate R&D for neglected needs.They are f<strong>in</strong>anced by philanthropic and public donors, who have collectively pledged morethan one billion US dollars to PPPs. Almost all PPPs have been created with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> last tenyears.14 Recall that TT is a decreas<strong>in</strong>g cost activity (chapter 2, section 3): <strong>the</strong> more extensive <strong>the</strong>experience previously acquired by <strong>the</strong> <strong>org</strong>anisations <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> process, <strong>the</strong> lower <strong>the</strong>transfer costs <strong>in</strong> relation to total project size.15 See Correa (2007) for a careful analysis and discussion of <strong>the</strong> country reports and moregenerally of <strong>the</strong> problems raised by <strong>the</strong> Article 66.2.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development59REFERENCESAbbott, F. 2003. The Competition Provisions <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> Agreement: Implications for <strong>Technology</strong><strong>Transfer</strong>. Presented at a jo<strong>in</strong>t WIPO-WTO workshop.Angeles, L. 2005. Should Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries Streng<strong>the</strong>n Their Intellectual Property Rights?Topics <strong>in</strong> Macroeconomics Vol.5, Issue 1.Appleyard M., Hatch N. and Mowery D., 1996. Manag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Development and <strong>Transfer</strong> of ProcessTechnologies <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Semiconductor Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g Industry. IIASA Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper.Arora, A., 1995. Licens<strong>in</strong>g Tacit Knowledge: Intellectual Property Rights and <strong>the</strong> Market for KnowHow. Economics of Innovation and New <strong>Technology</strong> Vol.4, Issue 1.Arora, A., 1996. Contract<strong>in</strong>g for Tacit Knowledge: The Provision of Technical Services <strong>in</strong> <strong>Technology</strong>Licens<strong>in</strong>g Contracts. Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 50.Arora, A., 2007. Intellectual Property Rights and <strong>the</strong> International <strong>Transfer</strong> of <strong>Technology</strong>: Sett<strong>in</strong>gOut an <strong>Age</strong>nda for Empirical Research <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries. WIPO Conference.Arora, A., Fosfuri, A. and Gambardella A., 2001. Specialized <strong>Technology</strong> Suppliers, InternationalSpillovers and Investment: Evidence From <strong>the</strong> Chemical Industry. Journal of DevelopmentEconomics Vol. 65.Arora A., Fosfuri, A. and Gambardella, A., 2002. Markets for <strong>Technology</strong>: Economics of Innovationand Corporate Strategy. Cambridge: MIT Press.Athreye, S and Cantwell, J., 2007. Creat<strong>in</strong>g competition? Globalisation and <strong>the</strong> Emergence of New<strong>Technology</strong> Producers. Research Policy Vol. 36, 2.Barton J., 2007. New Trends <strong>in</strong> <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>: Implications for National and InternationalPolicy. ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development, Issue Paper No.18,International Centre for Trade and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development, Geneva, Switzerland.Baumol, W., 2002. The Free Market Innovation Mach<strong>in</strong>e. Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton, New Jersey: Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton UniversityPress.Bessen, J. and Meurer, M., 2008. Patent Failure. Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton, New Jersey: Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton UniversityPress.Blomström, M. and Kokko, A., 1998. Foreign Investment as a Vehicle for International <strong>Technology</strong><strong>Transfer</strong>. In Creation and <strong>Transfer</strong> of Knowledge, ed. Navaretti, Dasgupta, Mäler andS<strong>in</strong>iscalco. New York: Spr<strong>in</strong>ger.Branstetter, L., Fisman R. and Fritz Foley C., 2005. Do Stronger IPR Increase TT? Empirical Evidencefrom US Firm Level Panel Data. New York: Columbia University.Branstetter, L., Fisman, R., Fritz Foley, C. and Saggi K., 2007. Intellectual Property Rights, Imitation,and Foreign Direct Investment: Theory and Evidence. NBER Work<strong>in</strong>g paper 13033.Byerlee, D. and Fischer K., 2002. Access<strong>in</strong>g Modern Science: Policy and Institutional Options forAgricultural Biotechnology <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries. World Development Vol.30, 6.


60 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesCassier, M. and Correa, M., 2005. Intellectual Property and Public Health: Copy<strong>in</strong>g of HIV/AIDS Drugsby Brasilian and Private Pharmaceutical Laboratories. Draft paper.Chooi, C., Chang, L. and Zhang, Y., 1994. <strong>Technology</strong> transfer and International Organizations: TheQuestion of Localisation. Science, <strong>Technology</strong> and Development 12(1/2).Cockurn, I., 2007. Is <strong>the</strong> Market for <strong>Technology</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g? Obstacles to Licens<strong>in</strong>g Inventions, andWays to Reduce Them. Paper presented at <strong>the</strong> Monte Verita Conference The Economics of<strong>Technology</strong> Policy <strong>in</strong> Ascona, Switzerland.Correa, C., 2007. Intellectual Property <strong>in</strong> LDCs: Strategies for Enhanc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> andDissem<strong>in</strong>ation. Background Paper No.4: UNCTAD: The Least Developed Country Report2007.Corsi, F., 2007. An Example of Use of Appropriate <strong>Technology</strong>: Sett<strong>in</strong>g Up of Hear<strong>in</strong>g Aid Facilities<strong>in</strong> Ethiopia. Draft Paper.David P.A. Institutional Lock In: The Path Dependent Evolution of Intellectual Property Rights and <strong>the</strong>Relentless Encroachment Upon <strong>the</strong> Public Knowledge ‘Commons’ <strong>in</strong> Science and <strong>Technology</strong>.Unpublished Draft.David P.A., 1996. Re-th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1990s: Incentives, Institutions andKnowledge-Based Industrial Development. In Ch<strong>in</strong>ese <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1990s:Current Experience, Historical Problems and International Perspectives, ed. Fe<strong>in</strong>ste<strong>in</strong> andHowe. United K<strong>in</strong>gdom: Edward Elgar.De Boer, Y. Address, 2008. European Patent Forum, Lubjlana, 2008Enos J., 1996. The Adoption of Innovations and <strong>the</strong> Assimilation of Improvements. In Ch<strong>in</strong>ese<strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1990s: Current Experience, Historical Problems and InternationalPerspectives, ed. Fe<strong>in</strong>ste<strong>in</strong> and Howe. United K<strong>in</strong>gdom: Edward Elgar.Enos J., 1998. In Pursuit of Science and <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa: The Impact of StructuralAdjustment Programs. UNU/INTECH Studies <strong>in</strong> New <strong>Technology</strong> and Development.Enos, J., Lall, S. and Yun M., 1998. <strong>Transfer</strong> of <strong>Technology</strong>: An Update. Asian-Pacific EconomicLiterature.European Community, 2007. Implementation of Article 66.2 of <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> Agreement. Presented at<strong>the</strong> WTO Council for <strong>TRIPS</strong> on February 12, IP/C/W/480/Add.5Foray D., 2004. The Economics of Knowledge. Cambridge: MIT Press.Ghosh R. and Soete L., 2006. Information and Intellectual Property. Work<strong>in</strong>g paper UNU-MERIT,Number 29.Hall, B., 2004. Government Policy for Innovation <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America. Regional Studies Program of <strong>the</strong>Chief Economist for Lat<strong>in</strong> America, <strong>the</strong> World Bank.Hall, B., 2001. The Global Nature of IP. Paper presented at <strong>the</strong> Toronto IP Conference <strong>in</strong> March.Hausmann, R. and Rodrik, D., 2002. Economic Development as Self-discovery. NBER Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper8952.


ICTSD Programme on IPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development61Hirsch, W., 1952. Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g Progress Functions. Review of Economics of Statistics, 34, 2.Ho, S., 1997. <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> to Ch<strong>in</strong>a Dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> 1980s- How effective? Some Evidence fromJiangsu. Pacific Affairs Vol.70, Number 1.Hobday M., 1995. East Asian Latecomer Firms: Learn<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>Technology</strong> of Electronics. WorldDevelopment 23(7).ICTSD, 2007. Views on <strong>the</strong> Future of <strong>the</strong> Intellectual Property System. ICTSD Programme onIntellectual Property Rights and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development, Selected Issue Brief No.1Karap<strong>in</strong>ar B. and Temmerman, M., 2007. Benefit<strong>in</strong>g From Biotechnology: Pro-poor IPRs and PublicprivatePartnerships. NCCR trade regulation (Swiss National Centre of Competence). Work<strong>in</strong>gpaper 2007/35.Kostecki, M., 2006. Intellectual Property and Economic Development: What Technical Assistanceto Redress <strong>the</strong> Balance <strong>in</strong> Favour of Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries. ICTSD Programme on IPR andSusta<strong>in</strong>able Development, Issue Paper number 14, International Centre for Trade andSusta<strong>in</strong>able Development, Geneva, Switzerland.Krugman P., 1979. Increas<strong>in</strong>g Returns, Monopolistic Competition and International Trade. Journal ofInternational Economics 9.Lanjouw, J., 1998. The Introduction of Pharmaceutical Product Patents <strong>in</strong> India: Heartless Exploitationof <strong>the</strong> Poor and Suffer<strong>in</strong>g? NBER Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper series 6366.Mansfield E., 1982. <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>, Innovation and Public Policy. In The <strong>Transfer</strong> and Utilizationof Technical Knowledge, Sahal. Lanham: Lex<strong>in</strong>gton Books.Mansfield E., 1995. Intellectual Property Protection, Direct Investment and <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>.International F<strong>in</strong>ance Corporation Discussion Paper 27.Maskus, K., 2004. Encourag<strong>in</strong>g International <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>. UNCTAD-ICTSD Programme onIPRs and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development, Issue Paper No.7, International Centre for Trade andSusta<strong>in</strong>able Development, Geneva, Switzerland.Mat<strong>the</strong>w, D., 2005. <strong>TRIPS</strong> Flexibilities and Access To Medic<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries: The ProblemWith Technical Assistance and Free Trade Agreement. EIPR.Maurer, S., Sali, A. and Rai, A., 2004. F<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g Cures for Tropical Disease: Is Open Source <strong>the</strong> Answer?Public Library of Science: Medic<strong>in</strong>e.Mendi, P., 2007. Trade <strong>in</strong> Disembodied <strong>Technology</strong> and Total Factor Productivity <strong>in</strong> OECD Countries.Research Policy, Vol. 36, No,1, 121-133.Moon, S., 2008. Does <strong>TRIPS</strong> Art.66.2 Encourage <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> to <strong>the</strong> LDCs? UNCTAD-ICTSDPolicy Brief No.2, Geneva.Moran, M., 2005. A Breakthrough <strong>in</strong> R&D for Neglected Diseases: New Ways to Get <strong>the</strong> Drugs WeNeed. PLoS Medic<strong>in</strong>e, 2(9).Polanyi, K., 1996. The Tacit Dimension. New York: Doubleday.


62 Dom<strong>in</strong>ique Foray — <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> <strong>Age</strong>: The Need for New Types of Partnershipsbetween <strong>the</strong> Least Developed and Most Advanced EconomiesRoffe, P. and Vivas D. (with G.Vea), 2007. Ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Policy Space for Development: A Case Studyon IP Technical Assistance <strong>in</strong> FTAs. ICTSD Programme on IPR and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development,Issue Paper No.19, International Centre for Trade and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development, Geneva,Switzerland.Samuelson P. and Scotchmer S., 2001. The Law and Economics of Reverse Eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g. University ofCalifornia at Berkeley.South Centre, 2005. The Potential Impacts of Nano-scale Technologies on Commodity Markets: TheImplications for Commodity Dependent Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries. T.R.A.D.E Research Paper 4.State Secretariat for Economic Affairs (SECO), 2005. Cleaner Production Centres: Swiss Support andExperience. Paper presented at <strong>the</strong> OECD workshop, “Multilateral environmental agreementsand private <strong>in</strong>vestment,” <strong>in</strong> Hels<strong>in</strong>ki, F<strong>in</strong>land.Stiglitz, J., 1991. Social Absorption Capability and Innovation. Stanford University CEPR Publicationnumber 292.Stiglitz, J. and Wallsten, S., 1999. Public-private Partnerships. American Behavioral Scientist,Vol.43, 1.Teece D., 1996. The Mult<strong>in</strong>ational Corporation and <strong>the</strong> Resource Cost of International <strong>Technology</strong><strong>Transfer</strong>. Cambridge: Bal<strong>in</strong>ger Books.Teece D., 1997. <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong> by Mult<strong>in</strong>ational Firms: The Resource Cost of <strong>Transfer</strong>r<strong>in</strong>gTechnological Know How. Economic Journal 87.Trajtenberg M., 2007. Innovation Policy for Development. Paper presented at <strong>the</strong> Monte VeritaConference The Economics of <strong>Technology</strong> Policy <strong>in</strong> Ascona, Switzerland.UNCTAD-ICTSD, 2005. Resource Book on <strong>TRIPS</strong> and Development. Cambridge: Cambridge UniversityPress.Von Hippel, E., 1994. Sticky Information and <strong>the</strong> Locus of Problem Solv<strong>in</strong>g: Implications for Innovation.Management Science, Vol.40, 4.World Bank, 2008. Global Economic Prospects. Wash<strong>in</strong>gton D.C.: The World Bank Group.World Intellectual Property Organization, 2006 and 2007. Patent Report Geneva: World IntellectualProperty Organization.


SELECTED ICTSD ISSUE PAPERSAgricultural Trade and Susta<strong>in</strong>able DevelopmentValue Cha<strong>in</strong>s and Tropical Products <strong>in</strong> a Chang<strong>in</strong>g Global Trade Regime. By Charles Ma<strong>the</strong>r. Issue Paper No. 13. May 2008Trade Effects of SPS and TBT Measures on Tropical and Diversification Products. By Anne-Celia Disdier, Belay Fekadu, Carlos Murillo, Sara A. Wong.Issue Paper No. 12. May 2008Tropical and Diversification Products Strategic Options for Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries. By Santiago Perry. Issue Paper No. 11.March 2008Implications of proposed modalities for <strong>the</strong> Special Safeguard Mechanism: a simulation exercise. Issue Paper No.10 Raul Montemayor, November 2007Trade and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Land Management <strong>in</strong> Drylands. Selected Issue Briefs, 2007.A Comparison of <strong>the</strong> Barriers Faced by Lat<strong>in</strong> American and ACP Countries’ Exports of Tropical Products.Issue Paper No. 9 by Jean-Christophe Bureau, Anne-Celia Disdier and Priscila Ramos, 2007.South-South Trade <strong>in</strong> Special Products. Issue Paper No.8 by Christopher Stevens, Jane Kennan and Mareike Meyn, 2007.Competitiveness and Susta<strong>in</strong>able DevelopmentLook<strong>in</strong>g for a mean<strong>in</strong>gful Duty Free Quota Free Market Access Initiative <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Doha Development <strong>Age</strong>nda. By David Laborde. Issue Paper No.4, 2007Impact of Orig<strong>in</strong> Rules for Textiles and Cloth<strong>in</strong>g on Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries. By Munir Ahmad. Issue Paper No.3, 2007Special and Differential Treatment for Small and Vulnerable Countries Based on <strong>the</strong> Situational Approach.Issue Paper No. 2 by Werner Corrales-Leal, Felipe Baritto, and Sarah A. Mohan, 2007.Basic Concepts and Proposals on <strong>the</strong> use of Policy Spaces <strong>in</strong> Trade-supported Strategies for Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development.Issue Paper No. 1 by Werner Corrales-Leal, 2007.Dispute Settlement and Legal Aspects of International TradeBurden of Proof <strong>in</strong> WTO Dispute Settlement: Contemplat<strong>in</strong>g Preponderance of Evidence Issue Paper No. 9 by James Headen Pfitzer and Sheila Sabune, 2009.Cross-Retaliation <strong>in</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong>: Options for Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries. Issue Paper No. 8 by Frederick. M Abbott, 2009.Suspension of Concessions <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Services Sector: Legal, Technical and Economic Problems.Issue Paper No. 7 by Arthur E. Appelton, JD, 2009.Trad<strong>in</strong>g Profiles and Develop<strong>in</strong>g Country Participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> WTO Dispute Settlement System.Issue Paper No. 6 by Joseph Francois and Henrik Horn, 2008.Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries, Countermeasures and WTO Law: Re<strong>in</strong>terpret<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> DSU aga<strong>in</strong>st <strong>the</strong> Background of International LawIssue Paper No. 5 by Andrea Bianchi and Lorenzo Gradoni, 2008.Does Legal Capacity Matter? Expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Dispute Initiation and Antidump<strong>in</strong>g actions <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> WTO.Issue Paper No. 4 by Marc L. Busch, Eric Re<strong>in</strong>hardt and Gregory Shaffer, 2008.Fisheries, International Trade and Susta<strong>in</strong>able DevelopmentFisheries, Aspects of ACP-EU Interim Economic Partnership Agreements: Trade and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development ImplicationsIssue Paper No.6, by Liam Campl<strong>in</strong>g, 2008Fisheries, International Trade and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development. Policy Discussion Paper, by ICTSD, 2006.Aquaculture: Issues and Opportunities for Susta<strong>in</strong>able Production and Trade. Issue Paper No. 5 by Frank Asche and Fahmida Khatun, 2006.Market Access and Trade Liberalisation <strong>in</strong> Fisheries. Issue Paper No. 4 by Mahfuz Ahmed, 2006.Trade and Marketplace Measures to Promote Susta<strong>in</strong>able Fish<strong>in</strong>g Practices. Issue Paper No. 3 by Cathy Roheim and Jon G. Sut<strong>in</strong>en, 2006.Fisheries Access Agreements: Trade and Development Issues. Issue Paper No. 2 by Stephen Mbithi Mwikya, 2006.Intellectual Property Rights and Susta<strong>in</strong>able DevelopmentThe Global Debate on <strong>the</strong> Enforcement of Intellectual Property Rights and Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries.Issue Paper No.22, 2009.Intellectual Property and Competition Law Issue Paper No.21, by Carlos M. Correa, 2007.Intellectual Property Provisions <strong>in</strong> European Union Trade Agreements: Implications for Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries.Issue Paper No. 20 by Maximiliano Santa Cruz S., 2007.Ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Policy Space for Development: A Case Study on IP Technical Assistance <strong>in</strong> FTAs.Issue Paper No. 19 by Pedro Roffe and David Vivas with G<strong>in</strong>a Vea, 2007.New Trends <strong>in</strong> <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>: Implications for National and International Policy. Issue Paper No. 18 by John H. Barton, 2007.Trade <strong>in</strong> Services and Susta<strong>in</strong>able DevelopmentMaritime Transport and Related Logistics Services <strong>in</strong> Egypt, by Ahmed F. Ghoneim, and Omneia A. Helmy, Issue Paper No 8, December 2007Opportunities and Risks of Liberalis<strong>in</strong>g Trade <strong>in</strong> Services <strong>in</strong> Pakistan, By Abid A. Burki, Issue Paper No 7, December 2007Regulatory Pr<strong>in</strong>ciples for Environmental Services and <strong>the</strong> General Agreement on Trade <strong>in</strong> Services, by Massimo Geloso Grosso, Issue Paper No 6,December 2007Opportunities and Risks of Liberalis<strong>in</strong>g Trade <strong>in</strong> Services <strong>in</strong> Mozambique, by Alberto Teodoro Bila, Eduardo Mondlane, Hélder Chambal and ViriatoTamele, Issue Paper No 5, December 2007Opportunities and Risks of Liberaliz<strong>in</strong>g Trade <strong>in</strong> Services <strong>in</strong> Tanzania, by Daima Associates Limited, National Consultant, Issue Paper No.4, December2007Trade and Susta<strong>in</strong>able EnergyClimate Change and Trade on <strong>the</strong> Road to Copenhagen Policy Discussion Paper, 2009.Trade, Climate Change and Global Competitiveness: Opportunities and Challenge for Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a and Beyond,Selected Issue Briefs No.3 by ICTSD, 2008.Intellectual Property and Access to Clean Energy Technologies <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries: An Analysis of Solar Photovoltaic, Biofuel and W<strong>in</strong>dTechnologies. Issue Paper No. 2 by John H. Barton, 2007.Climate, Equity, and Global Trade. Selected Issue Briefs No. 2, 2007.The WTO and Energy: WTO Rules and Agreements of Relevance to <strong>the</strong> Energy Sector. Issue Paper No. 1 by Julia Selivanova, 2007.L<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g Trade, Climate and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Energy. Selected Issue Briefs, 2006.These and o<strong>the</strong>r ICTSD resources are available at http://www.ictsd.<strong>org</strong>


www.ictsd.<strong>org</strong>The International Centre for Trade and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development (ICTSD) has been active <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> field of <strong>in</strong>tellectual propertys<strong>in</strong>ce 1997, amongst o<strong>the</strong>rs, through its Programme on Intellectual Property Rights (IPRs) and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development. Onecentral objective of <strong>the</strong> Programme has been to facilitate <strong>the</strong> emergence of a critical mass of well <strong>in</strong>formed stakeholders<strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g decision makers, negotiators as also <strong>the</strong> private sector and civil society who will be ableto def<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong>ir own susta<strong>in</strong>able human development objectives <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> field of IPRs and effectively advance <strong>the</strong>m at <strong>the</strong>national and <strong>in</strong>ternational levels.The Programme has generated an Issue Paper Series on Intellectual Property Rights and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development with <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>tention of offer<strong>in</strong>g a clear, jargon-free syn<strong>the</strong>sis of <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> issues to help policy makers, stakeholders and <strong>the</strong> public<strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g and developed countries to understand <strong>the</strong> vary<strong>in</strong>g perspectives surround<strong>in</strong>g different IPRs, <strong>the</strong>ir known orpossible impact on susta<strong>in</strong>able livelihoods and development, and different policy positions over <strong>the</strong> <strong>TRIPS</strong> Agreement ando<strong>the</strong>r relevant <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>tellectual property arrangements.This Issue Paper Series is <strong>the</strong> consequence of a participatory process <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g trade negotiators, national policy makers,as well as em<strong>in</strong>ent experts <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> field, <strong>the</strong> media, NGOs, <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>org</strong>anizations, and <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> North and <strong>the</strong>South deal<strong>in</strong>g with IPRs and development. Previous publications under this Series <strong>in</strong>clude:• The Global Debate on <strong>the</strong> Enforcement of Intellectual Property Rights and Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries.Issue Paper No.22, 2009.• Intellectual Property and Competition Law. Issue Paper No. 21 by Carlos M. Correa, 2007.• Intellectual Property Provisions <strong>in</strong> European Union Trade Agreements: Implications for Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries.IssuePaper No. 20 by Maximiliano Santa Cruz S., 2007.• Ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Policy Space for Development: A Case Study on IP Technical Assistance <strong>in</strong> FTAs.Issue Paper No. 19 by Pedro Roffe and David Vivas with G<strong>in</strong>a Vea, 2007.• New Trends <strong>in</strong> <strong>Technology</strong> <strong>Transfer</strong>: Implications for National and International Policy.Issue paper No. 18 by John H. Barton, 2007.• Exceptions to Patent Rights <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries.Issue paper No. 17 by Christopher Garrison, 2006.• Protect<strong>in</strong>g Traditional Knowledge: Pathways to <strong>the</strong> Future.Issue paper No. 16 by Graham Dutfield, 2006.• The International Copyright System: Limitations, Exceptions and Public Interest Considerations for Develop<strong>in</strong>gCountries.Issue Paper No. 15 by Ruth L. Okediji, 2006.• Intellectual Property and Economic Development: What Technical Assistance to Redress <strong>the</strong> Balance <strong>in</strong> Favour ofDevelop<strong>in</strong>g Nations?Issue Paper No. 14 by Michel Kosteki, 2006.• Utility Models and Innovation <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries.Issue Paper No.13 by Uma Su<strong>the</strong>rsanen, 2006.• Intellectual Property Provisions of Bilateral and Regional Trade Agreements <strong>in</strong> Light of US Federal Law.Issue Paper No.12 by Frederick M. Abbott, 2006.• Technical Assistance for <strong>the</strong> Formulation and Implementation of Intellectual Property Policy <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>gCountries and Transition Economies.Issue Paper No.11 by Tom Pengelly, 2005.ABOUT ICTSDFounded <strong>in</strong> 1996, <strong>the</strong> International Centre for Trade and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development (ICTSD) is an <strong>in</strong>dependent non-profitand non-governmental <strong>org</strong>anisation based <strong>in</strong> Geneva. By empower<strong>in</strong>g stakeholders <strong>in</strong> trade policy through <strong>in</strong>formation,network<strong>in</strong>g, dialogue, well targeted research and capacity build<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>the</strong> Centre aims to <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational tradesystem such that it advances <strong>the</strong> goal of susta<strong>in</strong>able development.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!