12.07.2015 Views

Making the Law W ork for Everyone - AL BACHARIA

Making the Law W ork for Everyone - AL BACHARIA

Making the Law W ork for Everyone - AL BACHARIA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Making</strong><strong>the</strong> <strong>Law</strong>W<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong><strong>Everyone</strong>Copyright © 2008by <strong>the</strong> Commission on Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorand United Nations Development Programme1 UN Plaza, New Y<strong>ork</strong>, New Y<strong>ork</strong>, 10017Cert no. SW-COC-1530Printed in <strong>the</strong> U.S.A. by Consolidated Graphics, A Forest Stewardship Council (FSC) certified company.Paper used is elemental chlorine free, acid free and Forest Stewardship Council certified. All inks arelow VOC and vegetable-based.


Preface *Success in endeavours of this kind draws from <strong>the</strong> contribution of a very large numberIn November 2006, a delegation from <strong>the</strong> Commission on Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor visited a teeming open air market (known as <strong>the</strong> ‘Toi market’) in an impoverishedneighborhood in Nairobi, Kenya. To picture <strong>the</strong> market, imagine a mall without walls–or, <strong>for</strong> that matter, a roof or a floor – where each business is represented by a smalltable or a blanket laid on <strong>the</strong> ground. Imagine, as well, a surrounding area that is notorious<strong>for</strong> poor sanitation, pollution and crime. Floods are frequent. About one personin five has HIV/AIDS. Most of <strong>the</strong> residents lack legal title to <strong>the</strong> ramshackle dwellings<strong>the</strong>y call home or to <strong>the</strong> tiny businesses upon which <strong>the</strong>y depend <strong>for</strong> a living. Theseare men and women who are vulnerable and disadvantaged in every way – except <strong>for</strong>one – <strong>the</strong>y are determined not to be victims.About a decade ago, <strong>the</strong> sellers in <strong>the</strong> market created a communal savings plan towhich each contributed fifteen cents a day. The money was used <strong>for</strong> small businessloans and to make civic improvements, such as a public bath. Fifteen cents a day mayseem a trifling sum, but in that place and <strong>for</strong> those people <strong>the</strong> payment often meant<strong>for</strong>going <strong>the</strong> purchase of new clo<strong>the</strong>s <strong>for</strong> a child, food <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> family, or a used bicycle<strong>for</strong> transportation. This was democracy at its purest – <strong>the</strong> willing surrender of a privatebenefit to build a ladder out of poverty <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> community as a whole. Proposals <strong>for</strong>loans and projects were approved openly and collectively, with consent signified by <strong>the</strong>wiggling of fingers and <strong>the</strong> clapping of hands. Over time, <strong>the</strong> fund grew by tiny incrementsto more than $200,000.This was still not much in a market with 5000 stalls crammed toge<strong>the</strong>r, sellingeverything from toys and cabbage and to spark plugs and flip-flops. Still, <strong>the</strong> savingsplan was a source of hope and pride to people who had put <strong>the</strong>ir faith in cooperativeaction, understood <strong>the</strong> importance of abiding by shared rules, and were doing everythingpossible to help <strong>the</strong>mselves. Their courage underlined our conviction that thosewho consider poverty to be just ano<strong>the</strong>r part of <strong>the</strong> human condition are ignorant, <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor do not accept it, and when given <strong>the</strong> chance, will seize <strong>the</strong> opportunity totrans<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong>ir lives. Because of what we saw and <strong>the</strong> people we met, <strong>the</strong> Commissionleft Nairobi encouraged.Then, in December 2007, Kenya held a presidential election. The voting was flawedand fights broke out. Hundreds of people died and <strong>the</strong> market we visited was completelydestroyed. There is literally nothing left.*reprinted from Volume I


In reply to its expression of sorrow and concern, <strong>the</strong> Commission received a letterfrom Joseph Muturi, one of <strong>the</strong> market leaders. He wrote that <strong>the</strong> social fabric builtup over decades had been torn, and that people had been <strong>for</strong>ced into exile in <strong>the</strong>irown country, simply because of <strong>the</strong>ir ethnicity. ‘We have gone back in time,’ he wrote,and ‘it will take us many years to come back to <strong>the</strong> level where we were both sociallyand economically.’ He observed that it had taken Kenyans to make Kenya; and nowKenyans had broken Kenya; but <strong>the</strong>y would – he was sure – recover it again, althoughat an expense of time and resources that could never fully be regained.The lesson is clear. When democratic rules are ignored and <strong>the</strong>re is no law capable ofproviding shelter, <strong>the</strong> people who suffer most are those who can least af<strong>for</strong>d to lose.Creating an infrastructure of laws, rights, en<strong>for</strong>cement, and adjudication is not anacademic project, of interest to political scientists and social engineers. The establishmentof such institutions can spell <strong>the</strong> difference between vulnerability and security,desperation and dignity <strong>for</strong> hundreds of millions of our fellow human beings.In his letter from <strong>the</strong> ruins of <strong>the</strong> Toi market, Joseph Muturi said that ‘<strong>the</strong> big taskthat has occupied me is to try to bring <strong>the</strong> people toge<strong>the</strong>r in order to salvage oursense of community.’ Creating a sense of mutual responsibility and community on aglobal basis is a key to fighting poverty and a challenge to us all. It is our hope thatthis Commission report, with its recommendations, will help point <strong>the</strong> way to that goaland to a better and more equitable future <strong>for</strong> us all.Respectfully,Madeleine K. AlbrightHernando de SotoCo-chairsCommission on Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor


AcknowledgmentsSuccess in endeavours of this kind draws from <strong>the</strong> contribution of a very large number ofpeople. We name several of <strong>the</strong>m below and apologise in advance to those whose namesare not mentioned.We acknowledge with thanks <strong>the</strong> valuable contributions of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing group chairs, rapporteurs,members of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups and associated experts.Chapter 1, Access to Justice and <strong>the</strong> Rule of <strong>Law</strong>, is <strong>the</strong> outcome of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing groupchaired by Commission member Lloyd Axworthy, <strong>for</strong>mer Minister of Foreign Affairs ofCanada and currently President and Vice Chancellor of <strong>the</strong> University of Winnipeg.Members and associated experts of <strong>the</strong> group included Maurits Barendrecht, Nina Berg,Christina Biebesheimer, James Goldston, Robert Kapp, Vivek Maru, Sam Mueller,Clotilde Medegan Nougbode, Richard E. Messick, Kathurima M’Inoti, Wendy Patten,Sonia Picado Robin Sully and Mat<strong>the</strong>w C. Stephenson, who also served as its rapporteuruntil June 2007 after which <strong>the</strong> group was supported by Maurits Barendrecht and NinaBerg.Chapter 2, Property Rights, is <strong>the</strong> outcome of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing group chaired by Commissionmember Ashraf Ghani, Dean of Kabul University and <strong>for</strong>mer Minister of Finance ofAfghanistan. Members and associated experts of <strong>the</strong> group included Liz Alden Wily, BanashreeBanerjee, Karol Boudreaux, Wolfgang Bruelhart, Anis Dani, Maleye Diop, SusanaLastarria-Cornhiel, Jon Lindsay, Sylvia Martínez, Paul Monro-Faure, Edgardo MosqueiraMedina, Rehman Sobhan, Gerardo Solis, and Belinda Yuen. Francis Cheneval, whoserved as <strong>the</strong> rapporteur, succeeding Robert Mitchell, presented <strong>the</strong> group’s findings andrecommendations.Chapter 3, Labour Rights, is <strong>the</strong> outcome of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing group chaired by Commissionmember Allan Larsson, <strong>for</strong>mer Swedish Finance Minister and currently Chairman of <strong>the</strong>Board, University of Lund, Sweden. Members and associated experts of <strong>the</strong> group includedAzita Berar-Awad, Haroon Bhorat, Steven Miller, Jamele Rigolini, Victor Tokman,and Rosanna Wong. Sandra Yu served as rapporteur until June 2007, after which MarthaChen and o<strong>the</strong>r members supported <strong>the</strong> group.Chapter 4, Business Rights, is <strong>the</strong> outcome of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing group chaired by Commissionmember Medhat Hassanein, <strong>for</strong>merly <strong>the</strong> Egyptian Minister of Finance. Members andassociated experts of <strong>the</strong> group include Martha Chen, Gabriel Daly, Claire More Dickerson,S Taher Helmy, Sunita Kapila, Arun Kashyap, Michael Henriques, Tanwir H Naqvi,Enrique Pasquel, Lucas Robinson, David Roll, Rehman Sobhan, Gerardo Solis, A JohnWatson. Asif Chida served as rapporteur.Chapter 5, Road Maps <strong>for</strong> Implementation of Re<strong>for</strong>ms, is <strong>the</strong> outcome of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ingi


group chaired by Commission members Hilde Frafjord Johnson, <strong>for</strong>mer Norwegian Ministerof International Development, and Milinda Moragoda, Sri Lanka’s <strong>for</strong>mer Ministerof Economic Re<strong>for</strong>ms, Science and Technology. Members and associated experts of <strong>the</strong>group included Maria Gonzalez de Asis, Christina Biebesheimer, Michael Bratton, DerickBrinkerhoff, Getachew Demeke, Lalanath de Silva, Philip Dobie, Szilard Fricska, TerenceJones, Daniel Kaufmann, Lily La Torre Lopez, Bruce Moore, Es<strong>the</strong>r Mwaura-Muiru, SheelaPatel, Arjun Sengupta, and Anne Trebilcock. Bibek Debroy served as rapporteur until August2007 and was succeeded by Arthur Goldsmith.Several members of <strong>the</strong> Secretariat supported <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong> of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups. Specialthanks go to Cate Ambrose and Parastoo Mesri who assisted in <strong>the</strong> establishment andearly guidance of <strong>the</strong> groups and also to Veronique Verbruggen who supervised <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups from November 2006 to November 2007. We are thankful to <strong>the</strong>members of <strong>the</strong> Secretariat <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir tireless ef<strong>for</strong>ts, particularly to Timothy Dolan <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> production of this publication and Jill Hannon <strong>for</strong> Secreteriat management. Specialthanks also go to Kristin Cullison <strong>for</strong> her support of our w<strong>ork</strong>. A long list of interns, includingSabiha Ahmed, Shailly Barnes, Wanning Chu, Francesco Di Stefano, Patricia de Haan,Ruth Guevara, Alena Herklotz, Brian Honermann, Emily Key, Rajju Malla-Dhakal, FarzanaRamzan, Erica Salerno, Alec Schierenbeck, Asrat Tesfayesus, Tara Zapp, and Luis Villanueva,supported <strong>the</strong> Commission.Apart from participating as members in our Commission, several multilateral institutions supported<strong>the</strong> activities of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups. ILO hosted meetings of w<strong>ork</strong>ing group three onlabour and one meeting of w<strong>ork</strong>ing group four on business rights, UN-Habitat and <strong>the</strong> WorldBank provided technical expertise in several areas of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong> of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups.We are grateful <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> pro bono w<strong>ork</strong> carried out by Baker and McKenzie, and Lex Mundi.We extend special thanks to our donors Canada, Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway,Sweden, Switzerland, Ireland, Spain, <strong>the</strong> United Kingdom, <strong>the</strong> African Development Bankand <strong>the</strong> European Commission whose generous contributions helped to make this Commissiona reality and to <strong>the</strong> in-kind support provided by USAID.We are also grateful to UNDP and its Administrator, Kemal Dervis, , <strong>for</strong> hosting <strong>the</strong> Commission.We are especially grateful <strong>the</strong> role played by Olav Kjørven and Maaike de Langen.Last, but not least, thanks go to Tevia Abrams <strong>for</strong> his editorial w<strong>ork</strong> and Cynthia Spence<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> design and layout of this publication.Co-chair Executive Director Co-chairii


IntroductionCo-chaired by <strong>for</strong>mer US Secretary of State, Madeleine Albright and Peruvian economistHernando de Soto, <strong>the</strong> Commission on Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor is <strong>the</strong> firstglobal initiative to focus specifically on <strong>the</strong> link between exclusion, poverty and law.Poverty manifests itself in multiple ways. One of <strong>the</strong> staggering facts about povertyis that <strong>the</strong> vast majority of <strong>the</strong> world’s economy lives <strong>the</strong>ir daily lives in what is oftenreferred to as <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal or extralegal sector. At all levels (individual, family, communityand national) <strong>the</strong> lack of access to effective legal protection and <strong>for</strong>mal policy andwelfare systems, as well as a lack of recognition of economic assets/activities, worsensexisting vulnerabilities and fur<strong>the</strong>r constrains <strong>the</strong> economic and social developmentopportunities of <strong>the</strong> poor. When <strong>the</strong> majority of <strong>the</strong> world’s populations live <strong>the</strong>ir livesin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector, and <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy is dwarfed by <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal, <strong>the</strong> resultis lower growth, less revenue and less room <strong>for</strong> investment in health, education andinfrastructure. In addition, corruption and <strong>the</strong> resulting governance problems mayaffect <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector even more than <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal sector; this is significant due to<strong>the</strong> known negative impact on economic development, poverty reduction and effectivesocial service provision.The Commission’s unique mission is built on <strong>the</strong> conviction that poverty can only bereduced if governments give all citizens, especially <strong>the</strong> poor, a legitimate stake in <strong>the</strong>protections provided by <strong>the</strong> legal system, which should not be <strong>the</strong> privilege of <strong>the</strong> fewbut <strong>the</strong> right of everyone. Thus <strong>the</strong> Commission sets out to explore how nations canreduce poverty through re<strong>for</strong>ms that expand access to legal protection and opportunities<strong>for</strong> all. The Commission, which is composed of policymakers from all over <strong>the</strong>world with long experience leading re<strong>for</strong>m initiatives, is unique in that it seeks to solveproblems as opposed to deliberating <strong>the</strong>m.There are both similarities and differences in <strong>the</strong> way countries around <strong>the</strong> world, andover time, have approached <strong>the</strong> challenge of legal empowerment. These experiencesare only partly understood, both in terms of <strong>the</strong>ir key attributes and <strong>the</strong>ir outcomes.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong>re has been no systematic ef<strong>for</strong>t to compare or syn<strong>the</strong>sise lessonslearned across global experience in this area. One of <strong>the</strong> essential tasks of <strong>the</strong> Commissionis to examine a representative selection of such experiences in order to identifypromising re<strong>for</strong>m paths and tools. Ultimately <strong>the</strong> Commission seeks to use <strong>the</strong>seexperiences to influence real outcomes on <strong>the</strong> ground. In order to succeed, <strong>the</strong> Commissionmust achieve fundamental change in relation to how international developmentinstitutions approach development and poverty reduction, as well as capture <strong>the</strong> publicinterest around <strong>the</strong> world and stimulate demand <strong>for</strong> such changes at all levels.One of <strong>the</strong> objectives of <strong>the</strong> Commission is to legally empower in<strong>for</strong>mal sector actorsiii


so that <strong>the</strong>ir in<strong>for</strong>mal contracts have <strong>the</strong> protection of <strong>the</strong> law, and that a safe, secureand equitable way is found <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir integration within <strong>the</strong> mainstream economy. Thisis considered necessary <strong>for</strong> empowering <strong>the</strong>m to derive due benefits from <strong>the</strong> growingnational and global economy.The key elements of <strong>the</strong> strategy to achieve <strong>the</strong> desired outcomes are as follows:• Create political climate <strong>for</strong> change.• Syn<strong>the</strong>size global knowledge relevant to <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agenda. To this end,four areas of focus have been identified: Access to Justice and Rule of <strong>Law</strong>, PropertyRights, Labour Rights, and Legal Mechanisms to Empower In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses.W<strong>ork</strong>ing groups have been established around each of <strong>the</strong>se <strong>the</strong>mes. A rapporteur ortechnical team-leader, who w<strong>ork</strong>s closely with <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing group Chair (a member of<strong>the</strong> Commission), to coordinate its w<strong>ork</strong>, manages each w<strong>ork</strong>ing group.• Promote <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agenda at national and regional level and capturelocal experiences.• Develop policy recommendations and tools that will guide policymakers in <strong>the</strong> implementationof re<strong>for</strong>ms at <strong>the</strong> country level.Gender equality and <strong>the</strong> rights of indigenous communities are central to <strong>the</strong> legalempowerment agenda. These issues have been mainstreamed across <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong> of <strong>the</strong>Commission, and specific strategies and recommendations have been generated in allits areas of w<strong>ork</strong>.This is <strong>the</strong> second of two volumes of <strong>the</strong> report of <strong>the</strong> Commission on Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor and consists mainly of <strong>the</strong> outcomes of five w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups establishedto in<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> Commission’s deliberations through substantive w<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong><strong>the</strong>matic areas of Access to Justice and Rule of <strong>Law</strong>, Property Rights, Labour Rights,Business Rights and with respect to overall implementation strategies. The w<strong>ork</strong>inggroups consisted of a core of between five and seven experts and stakeholders in <strong>the</strong>irindividual capacities from around <strong>the</strong> world, with leading edge expertise and experiencein <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>me to be studied.Each chapter is devoted to <strong>the</strong> findings of one of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups and numberedaccordingly.Chapter 1, Access to Justice and Rule of <strong>Law</strong>, focuses on how <strong>the</strong> poor can be legallyempowered and poverty reduced by improving access to justice and expanding <strong>the</strong>rule of law, as defined by national views and structures. The w<strong>ork</strong>ing group considered<strong>the</strong> top-down and bottom-up processes necessary <strong>for</strong> generating effective re<strong>for</strong>ms andpractical recommendations, and examined <strong>the</strong> legal tools accessible to all citizens soiv


that <strong>the</strong>y can protect <strong>the</strong>ir assets and use <strong>the</strong>m to create trust, obtain credit, captureinvestment, access markets, raise productivity and protect <strong>the</strong>ir rights.Chapter 2, Property Rights, examines how <strong>the</strong> poor can be legally empowered andpoverty reduced when <strong>the</strong>y have fungible rights over property and o<strong>the</strong>r assets in atransparent and functional manner. Because capital has a tendency to concentrate,contributing to <strong>the</strong> economic exclusion of marginalized groups, legal systems, whichgive <strong>the</strong> poor access to structured businesses, expanded markets and labour rights arerequired <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir legal empowerment.Chapter 3, Labour Rights, looks into how <strong>the</strong> poor can be legally empowered andpoverty reduced when <strong>the</strong> gap between <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>mal economy is bridgedand labour rights are respected. The w<strong>ork</strong>ing group studied <strong>the</strong> factors that constrainparticipation in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy and <strong>the</strong> challenges to en<strong>for</strong>cing labour rights. Thegroup made practical recommendations on how to facilitate convergence between <strong>for</strong>maland in<strong>for</strong>mal systems and <strong>the</strong> en<strong>for</strong>cement of labour standards.Chapter 4, Business Rights, studies <strong>the</strong> factors that preclude <strong>the</strong> poor from benefitingfrom full participation in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy, with a specific focus on <strong>the</strong> regulatoryenvironment <strong>for</strong> micro, small and medium sized businesses. It also examined localfinancial capacity and incentives <strong>for</strong> lenders to expand access to credit <strong>for</strong> individualsand enterprises owned or operated by <strong>the</strong> poor.Chapter 5, Road Maps <strong>for</strong> Implementation of Re<strong>for</strong>ms, syn<strong>the</strong>sises <strong>the</strong> key practicaloutputs of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong> of <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r chapters / w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups into a tool kit <strong>for</strong> useby policymakers around <strong>the</strong> world. W<strong>ork</strong> in this chapter draws on existing guidelines,framew<strong>ork</strong>s, manuals, indices, indicators and o<strong>the</strong>r related aids, which can help <strong>the</strong>key audiences of <strong>the</strong> Commission and facilitate <strong>the</strong> implementation of its policy recommendations.The aim of <strong>the</strong> tool kit is to support policymakers in proposing re<strong>for</strong>msand, once implemented, in measuring <strong>the</strong>ir results.The chapters contained in this volume reflect <strong>the</strong> views of <strong>the</strong> respective w<strong>ork</strong>ing groupmembers, though not necessarily <strong>the</strong> view of <strong>the</strong> Commission.Naresh C. Singh,Executive Director of <strong>the</strong> Commissionv


Table of contentsChapter 1 Access to Justice and <strong>the</strong> Rule of <strong>Law</strong>......................................... 1Introduction ...................................................................................................... 1An Access to Justice Cornerstone: Legal Identity...................................................... 4The Nature of <strong>the</strong> Problem .............................................................................. 4Addressing <strong>the</strong> Causes of <strong>the</strong> Legal Identity Crisis: Incapacity,Exclusion, and Avoidance ............................................................................... 5Streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong> Capacity of <strong>the</strong> Registration System ................................... 6Reducing Political Opposition to Full Registration .......................................... 9Providing In<strong>for</strong>mation and Creating Incentives to Register ............................. 10Strategies to Create Af<strong>for</strong>dable, Inclusive and Fair Justice ....................................... 12The Nature of <strong>the</strong> Problem ............................................................................ 12The Social Realities of Access to Justice ..................................................... 12Increasing Quality and Reducing Transaction Costs ...................................... 15Enabling Self Help with In<strong>for</strong>mation and Community Organising ....................... 18In<strong>for</strong>mation about Norms: Legal Education .................................................. 19Self Help Interventions: Forming of Peer Groups .......................................... 22Broadening <strong>the</strong> Scope of Legal Services <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor ....................................... 23Lower Cost Delivery Models: Paralegals ....................................................... 24Legal Services that Empower <strong>the</strong> Clients ..................................................... 25Alternative Dispute Resolution ................................................................... 25Bundling with O<strong>the</strong>r Services ..................................................................... 27Removing Constrictions of <strong>the</strong> Supply of Legal Services to <strong>the</strong> Poor ............... 28Financing of Claims: Legal Insurance and Targeted Legal Aid ........................ 31Reducing Transaction Costs: Wholesale Re<strong>for</strong>ms ............................................. 36Standard Routes <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Most Urgent Legal Needs ....................................... 37Bundling Claims: Class Actions .................................................................. 39O<strong>the</strong>r Ways to Reduce Costs of Access Wholesale ......................................... 40Improving In<strong>for</strong>mal and Customary Dispute Resolution .................................... 42Education and Awareness Campaigns ......................................................... 43Tailored Legal Aid Services ........................................................................ 44Targeted Constraints on In<strong>for</strong>mal Justice ..................................................... 44Structuring Institutional Relationships ........................................................ 45Improving Access to Justice in <strong>the</strong> Government Bureaucracy .................................... 47The Nature of <strong>the</strong> Problem ............................................................................ 49Public Administration Re<strong>for</strong>m ....................................................................... 49


External Monitoring ................................................................................... 49Structural Re<strong>for</strong>ms .................................................................................... 50Administrative <strong>Law</strong> Re<strong>for</strong>m ........................................................................... 53Legal Mechanisms to Facilitate Participation and Monitoring ........................ 53Judicial Review of Administrative Decisions................................................. 54Conclusions and Recommendations ............................................................ 56Chapter 1 Endnotes ..................................................................................... 58Chapter 1 Bibliography ................................................................................. 58Boxes1 Rule of <strong>Law</strong> and Justice ........................................................................... 32 Coping with Legal Pluralism in Relations to Women’s Rights in Ethiopia ...... 46Tables1 Needs <strong>for</strong> Norms and Interventions .......................................................... 15Chapter 2 Empowering <strong>the</strong> Poor Through Property Rights ......................... 63Introduction .................................................................................................... 73Faltering Property Rights: The Nature And Scale Of The Problem.............................. 76Growing Slums and Legal Voids ..................................................................... 76Dire Consequences and Missed Development Opportunities .......................... 76Rural Poverty and Property Rights ................................................................. 77Rural Land Relations and Extreme Poverty .................................................. 77Rural Land Relations and Armed Conflict .................................................... 77Natural Resources ........................................................................................ 77Women Especially Affected ........................................................................... 77Indigenous Peoples ...................................................................................... 78Focus on Indigenous Tenure Systems .......................................................... 79Important Numbers of Customary Land Holders ........................................... 79Refugees, Internally Displaced Persons .......................................................... 80Barriers Versus Facilitators of Change ................................................................. 80Resistance of Powerful Social Actors ............................................................. 80Structural Obstacles and Facilitators of Change .............................................. 80Realising Turnaround .................................................................................. 81Learning From The Past ..................................................................................... 82Problematic Practices and Omissions ............................................................ 82Six General Lessons from Past Mistakes are Presented as Follows: ................ 82Lessons From Mistakes Related to Land and Real Property ........................... 83Experienced Consequences........................................................................ 85Recommendations For Re<strong>for</strong>m And Improved Action................................................ 86


Re<strong>for</strong>ming Rules Regarding Bearers and Bundles of Property Rights ................. 86Individual and Common Private Property ..................................................... 87Recognising Customary Tenure and Communities as Bearers ofProperty Rights to Land and Natural Resources ........................................... 88Critical Issues in <strong>the</strong> Recognition of Customary and Indigenous Tenure Systems ...90Measures to Make Property Systems More Gender Equitable ......................... 91Intellectual Property Rights and <strong>the</strong> Rights of Indigenous Peoples:The Task Ahead ........................................................................................ 92Re<strong>for</strong>ming Property Governance in View of <strong>the</strong> Least Advantaged Customer ....... 94Changing Legislation ................................................................................. 94Re<strong>for</strong>m Priorities in Land and Real Property Administration .......................... 95Increasing Transparency in Public Land Use and Planning ............................ 96Zoning and City Planning ........................................................................... 97Implementation and Dispute Settlement ..................................................... 99Re<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>the</strong> Property System as a Market of Assets <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor .................. 100Market Development ............................................................................... 100Moveable and Intangible Property: A Missing Piece of <strong>the</strong> Development Puzzle ...102Equity Based Asset-Building <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor ..................................................... 103Creating Property Value <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor by Shareholder Systems ...................... 103Enhancing Access to Land and Real Property ............................................ 105The Beneficial Effects of Property Related Education and Relevant In<strong>for</strong>mation ..106Promoting Access to Housing ................................................................... 106Public Private Partnerships ...................................................................... 108Fostering Citizenship and Legal Empowerment through Consultation,In<strong>for</strong>mation and Participatory Property Re<strong>for</strong>mRecommendations <strong>for</strong> Policy Design and Sequencing ................................. 110What can Donor Countries and Multilateralism do <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Promotion ofProperty Rights and <strong>the</strong> Global Poor ......................................................... 112Concluding Message .................................................................................. 114Chapter 2 Endnotes ................................................................................... 115Chapter 2 Bibliography ............................................................................... 121Boxes 1 The world’s poor: a demographic note ............................................... 62 Acquiring property rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor ............................................. 883 Namibian land re<strong>for</strong>m .................................................................... 894 Focus Africa ................................................................................. 915 Sale of land: examples of legal issues ........................................... 1016 The Grameen Bank ...................................................................... 1047 Mexico: The Poor Rely on Pawnshops Instead of Banks ................... 1058 Example of Singapore: Public Housing as Economic Stimulant ........ 1079 Singapore: Importance of W<strong>ork</strong>ers’ Central Provident Fund .............. 108


10 Slum Upgrading Initiative in Dali<strong>for</strong>t, Senegal.............................. 10911 Peru Regularizes <strong>the</strong> Process of Titling Property Within Settlements . 110Tables 1 Mapping <strong>the</strong> Dynamics of Legal Status ........................................... 692 The Rural Poor in <strong>the</strong> Poorest Regions of <strong>the</strong> World .......................... 783 Main Regions Where Customary Land Tenure Operates ..................... 79Chapter 3 Towards a Global Social Contract:Labour Rights <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor ................................... 129Purpose of this Chapter ................................................................................... 131Introduction: Purpose of our Focus on Labour Rights............................................. 136Labour Rights, In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy, Empowerment and Decent W<strong>ork</strong>:What do we Mean? ......................................................................................... 137Labour Rights ............................................................................................ 137In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy ...................................................................................... 137Legal Empowerment ................................................................................... 137Decent W<strong>ork</strong> .............................................................................................. 138In<strong>for</strong>mality and Poverty: Whom are we talking about? What is <strong>the</strong>ir identity?............. 138Size and Significance in Developing Countries .............................................. 138Composition of <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy .......................................................... 139Segmentation in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Labour Market ................................................ 140In<strong>for</strong>malization of Labour Markets ............................................................... 142Gendered patterns ..................................................................................... 143In<strong>for</strong>malisation of Labour Markets by Sex .................................................. 143In<strong>for</strong>mal Employment in Developing Countries ........................................... 144Non-Standard Employment in Developed Countries .................................... 144Indigenous and Tribal Peoples .................................................................. 145Conclusions............................................................................................ 146Poverty and Labour Rights: a new departure........................................................ 147Poverty: A Market Failure and a Public Policy Failure .................................... 147A New Departure: Fundamental Principles and Rights at W<strong>ork</strong>, <strong>the</strong>Decent W<strong>ork</strong> Agenda, and Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> W<strong>ork</strong>ing Poor ............. 149Towards a Global Social Contract ................................................................. 151Labour Rights <strong>for</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal W<strong>ork</strong>ers: What is an Achievable Minimum Floor? . 152Business and Labour Rights at W<strong>ork</strong> ......................................................... 154Social Protection <strong>for</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal W<strong>ork</strong>ers ...................................................... 154The Role and Limitations of Voluntary Codes of Conduct ............................. 155Labour Rights, Social Protection, Employment Creation:trade-offs or complementarities? .............................................................. 156Conclusions............................................................................................... 157


The Economics of In<strong>for</strong>mality and <strong>the</strong> Debate on Labour Regulations ...................... 157The Economic Impact of Labour Regulation: An Overview of Key Results......... 158The Consequences of Labour Market Regulation ........................................ 159The Impact of Labour Market Regulation: Country Studies .......................... 161Towards a More Nuanced Understanding of Labour Regulations ...................... 162Interpretation of Regulations .................................................................... 163The Institutional Environment .................................................................. 164Heterogeneity in <strong>the</strong> Regulatory Architecture ............................................. 164Conclusions............................................................................................... 165Principles and Practices of Labour Rights and Legal Empowerment ................................The Basis Principles <strong>for</strong> Inclusive Re<strong>for</strong>mBoth Promotion of Change — and Management of Change .......................... 166Both Property Rights — and Labour Rights ............................................... 166Lessons from National Re<strong>for</strong>m Practice ........................................................ 167Legal Identity ......................................................................................... 167Voice and Representation ........................................................................ 167Social Protection Re<strong>for</strong>m ......................................................................... 168Improvement of <strong>the</strong> Quality of Labour Market Institutions ........................... 168Legal Empowerment Through Alternative Dispute Resolution ....................... 169Improved Business Environment ............................................................... 169Simplification of Contracting Procedures ................................................... 169Conclusions <strong>for</strong> National Strategies <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowerment ........................... 170Towards a new social contract: Policies and Processes <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowerment........ 170Policy Recommendations ............................................................................ 170Process Recommendations ......................................................................... 173Towards a New Social Contract .................................................................... 175Annex 1........................................................................................................ 176Recent and Current Initiatives to Improve Statistics on <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal ............... 176Annex 2........................................................................................................ 177Case 1 Extending Thailand’s Labour <strong>Law</strong> Through <strong>the</strong> MinisterialRegulation <strong>for</strong> Home W<strong>ork</strong>ers ...................................................................... 177Case 2 Judicial Ruling in <strong>the</strong> Philippines on Employment Relationship ........... 177Case 3 Welfare Fund in India ...................................................................... 178Case 4 Collective Identity, Collective Bargaining and Global Impact ................ 179Case 5 Federation of Urban Poor Participating in Governance ........................ 180Case 6 Legislative Initiatives <strong>for</strong> Unorganised W<strong>ork</strong>ers ................................... 182Case 7 Social Security <strong>for</strong> all in <strong>the</strong> Philippines ............................................ 183Case 8 Minimum Living Standard Security System in China ........................... 184Case 9 Labour protection <strong>for</strong> subcontracts in Chile ........................................ 184


Case 10 Spain: Flexibility at <strong>the</strong> Margin ....................................................... 185Case 11 China’s Positive Responses to Growing Market Economy ................... 186Case 12 Out-of-court Dispute Resolution as a Practical Tool <strong>for</strong> LegalEmpowerment ........................................................................................... 187Case 13 Revising bidding and procurement practices in Senegal .................... 187Chapter 3 Endnotes ................................................................................... 189Chapter 3 Bibliography ............................................................................... 191Boxes 1 Different Categories of In<strong>for</strong>mal W<strong>ork</strong>ers and Corresponding Challenges ..1412 Relationships Between In<strong>for</strong>mality and Growth: Cross-country Evidence .1423 ILO’s Convention on Indigenous and Tribal Peoples 1989 (No. 169) 1454 Social case <strong>for</strong> Labour Regulation ................................................. 1485 ILO Conventions and Recommendations Pertinent to <strong>the</strong>In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy .......................................................................... 150Figures 1 Segmentation in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Labour Market .................................. 140Tables 1 Mean Measures of Regulation, by Income Level.............................. 158Chapter 4 Business Rights ........................................................................ 195The In<strong>for</strong>mal Entrepreneur .......................................................................... 197Legal Empowerment and Legal Identity ........................................................ 198An Integrated Economy Approach ................................................................ 199The Re<strong>for</strong>m Agenda ................................................................................... 200Introduction and Framew<strong>ork</strong> ............................................................................. 202Why Business Rights? And Why Now? .......................................................... 203In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy and In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses .................................................. 204Legal Empowerment and Business Rights..................................................... 205Balancing Human Rights and Market-Based Approach ................................... 205Voice, Representation and Effective Economic Governance ............................ 206Greater Access to Markets, Goods and Services, and Infrastructure ................. 207Inclusive Financial Services ........................................................................ 207Institutional Changes ................................................................................. 208Pursuing <strong>the</strong> Agenda <strong>for</strong> Change .................................................................. 209To Sum Up ................................................................................................ 210In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy and In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses .................................................. 210In<strong>for</strong>mal-Formal Continuum ........................................................................ 210Poverty and In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy .................................................................... 211In<strong>for</strong>mal Enterprises ................................................................................... 211In<strong>for</strong>mal Enterprises and Productivity .......................................................... 212Mapping of In<strong>for</strong>mal Economies .................................................................. 214Women in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy ................................................................. 215


Indigenous Peoples and In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses ................................................ 216Empowering In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses ................................................................ 217To Sum Up ................................................................................................ 219Business Rights: Unlocking Barriers/Constraints to Empower In<strong>for</strong>mal Enterprises ............220Barriers and Constraints to Business Rights .................................................. 222Legal, Regulatory and Administrative Barriers ............................................... 223Costs of In<strong>for</strong>mality .................................................................................... 227Rights-based Legal Empowerment ............................................................... 229To sum up ................................................................................................. 230Empowering In<strong>for</strong>mal Enterprises Through Access to Markets, Goods and Services,and Infrastructure .......................................................................................... 230Improving <strong>the</strong> Functioning of Markets .......................................................... 230Increasing Access to Goods and Services...................................................... 232Inclusive Financial Services ........................................................................ 234Microfinance ............................................................................................. 235Savings ..................................................................................................... 236Micro-insurance ......................................................................................... 236Remittances .............................................................................................. 237Public Private Partnerships ......................................................................... 239To Sum Up ................................................................................................ 241Institutional Changes and Legal Tools <strong>Making</strong> a Difference <strong>for</strong> In<strong>for</strong>malEnterprises — an Evidence-based Approach ..................................................... 242Innovations which Demonstrate Business Rights and Legal Empowerment ....... 244Starting a Business ................................................................................. 244Operating a Business .............................................................................. 247Expansion .............................................................................................. 248En<strong>for</strong>cing Contracts ................................................................................ 250Exit ....................................................................................................... 251Successful Initiatives taken by Businesses ................................................ 251An Integrated Economy Approach ................................................................ 253To Sum Up ................................................................................................ 255Pursuing <strong>the</strong> Agenda <strong>for</strong> Change ....................................................................... 256Changes have to be Context Specific ............................................................ 257Re<strong>for</strong>m Processes Must Be Participatory and Gender Responsive .................... 257Legal Empowerment of In<strong>for</strong>mal Business Should be Prioritized as aGgovernance Issue ..................................................................................... 257Strategies and Institutions to Support In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses ............................ 258Market Based Institutions <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor ......................................................... 259Adding Value and Supply Chain to <strong>the</strong> Labour of <strong>the</strong> Poor and In<strong>for</strong>malBusinesses ................................................................................................ 259


Taking Microcredit Out of <strong>the</strong> Ghetto ........................................................... 259Mutual Funds <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor .......................................................................... 260Institutionalising <strong>the</strong> Collective Identity of Poor and In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses ........ 261Business Rights - Provides Value Based Change Process ................................ 262Pillars of Change ....................................................................................... 263Conclusions............................................................................................... 265Recommendations and Key Messages .......................................................... 266Objectives of Empowerment Process ......................................................... 266Means to Meet Objectives ........................................................................ 266The Formalisation Debate ........................................................................ 266Chapter 4 Endnotes ................................................................................... 267Chapter 4 Bibliography ............................................................................... 271Boxes 1 Empowering Indigenous People through Entrepreneurship ............... 2172 Unlocking Barriers: Legal Mechanisms to Empower In<strong>for</strong>malBusinesses .................................................................................... 2213 Most Difficult Places to Do Business (by specific category) .............. 2244 Largest Multi-National Company has 2.3 Million Rural Poor Womenas Shareholders ............................................................................. 260Case StudiesUkraine and Private Business Development ............................................... 226New Markets Lead to New Opportunities <strong>for</strong> Rural In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses—VegCARE, Kenya ..................................................................................... 232Linking Markets: Promoting Sustainable Tourism Development withIndigenous and Rural Communitiesin Latin America ................................... 234Alternate Model of In<strong>for</strong>mal Credit: SMEs Helping In<strong>for</strong>mal Enterprises in Peru ..235Construmex (Mexico) — Helping Migrants with Remittances ....................... 238Durban: A Heterogeneous Solution Through Public Private Partnership ........ 240Buy-back Centres <strong>for</strong> Waste Collectors: A Public-Private-CommunityPartnership Model .................................................................................. 240“Tell us How to Make Legal Mechanisms and Tools W<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> In<strong>for</strong>malBusinesses.” President Benjamin Mkapa, Tanzania .................................... 243Business Registration Re<strong>for</strong>m in Uganda ................................................... 245Identity, Voice And Association In The In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy —A Long Journey Of Self-employed Women’s Association (Sewa), India .......... 254Technology and <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector: Fishing with Mobile Phones ................ 258Figures 1 GDP Per Capita and <strong>the</strong> Size of <strong>the</strong> Shadow Economy ..................... 2132 Indigenous Private Sector Development and Regulation in Africa andCentral Europe: A 10-country Study ................................................. 2133 Regulatory Burdens Impacting on In<strong>for</strong>mal Enterprises ................... 2234 Regulatory Environment and In<strong>for</strong>mality ........................................ 2255 Legal Empowerment of In<strong>for</strong>mal Enterprises .................................. 263


Chapter 5 Road Maps <strong>for</strong> Implementation of Re<strong>for</strong>ms:Implementation Strategies, Including Toolkits and Indices ..................... 275Road Maps to Implementation .................................................................... 278Mapping Legal Empowerment beyond <strong>the</strong> Nation State .................................. 279Toolkits and Indices ................................................................................... 279Strategy and Tactics ................................................................................... 281Introduction: Attributes of Legal Empowerment .................................................... 283Implementation: Challenges and Opportunities .................................................... 285Policy Initiation ......................................................................................... 287Policy Champions ...................................................................................... 288Forces Affecting Implementation ................................................................. 289Policy Stakeholders .................................................................................... 290Beneficiaries ............................................................................................. 291Allies ........................................................................................................ 294Practitioners.............................................................................................. 295Challengers ............................................................................................... 295Policy Environment and Contextual Analysis ................................................. 296Social Structure ......................................................................................... 296Economic Context ...................................................................................... 297Political System ......................................................................................... 298Administrative State ................................................................................... 300In<strong>for</strong>mality ................................................................................................ 302Policy Characteristics ................................................................................. 308Complexity ................................................................................................ 308Ambiguity ................................................................................................. 309Discord ..................................................................................................... 310Diagnosing <strong>the</strong> Influence on Policy Implementation ....................................... 312An Approach to Implementation <strong>for</strong> Country ‘X’............................................. 312Road Maps to Implementation .......................................................................... 315Mapping <strong>the</strong> Empowerment Domains ........................................................... 316Mapping <strong>the</strong> LEP Agenda at Different Political/Administrative Levels .............. 322Activities at Global Level ............................................................................ 323Activities at <strong>the</strong> Regional and Sub-regional Levels ......................................... 324Activities at National Level ......................................................................... 325Activities at <strong>the</strong> Local Level ........................................................................ 325Country Level Approaches, Toolkits and Indices................................................... 325Countries Piloting Legal Empowerment Re<strong>for</strong>m ............................................. 325Choosing <strong>the</strong> Appropriate Country Level Process ........................................... 326Tools to Support Legal Empowerment Re<strong>for</strong>ms .............................................. 328


Explanation of <strong>the</strong> Tools ............................................................................. 328Ready-made Indicators of Legal Empowerment ............................................. 328Monitoring and Evaluation ............................................................................... 329Strategy and Tactics ................................................................................... 332Strategic Findings ................................................................................... 333Tactical Ideas ......................................................................................... 334Annex 1: Policy Implementation Tools................................................................ 337Annex 2: Existing Toolkits: An Inventory ............................................................. 342Access to jJstice ........................................................................................ 342Property Rights .......................................................................................... 342Labour Rights ............................................................................................ 343Business ................................................................................................... 344Annex 3: Existing Indicators and Indices — An Inventory ...................................... 345Access to Justice ....................................................................................... 345Property Rights .......................................................................................... 346Labour Rights ............................................................................................ 347Business ................................................................................................... 348Chapter 5 Endnotes ........................................................................................ 350Chapter 5 Bibliography ................................................................................... 352Boxes 5.1 Removing Barriers to Public W<strong>ork</strong>s Contracts .............................. 2865.2 Ancestral Domain Sustainable Development and ProtectionPlan of <strong>the</strong> Bago and Bugkalot Tribes ............................................... 2935.3 Empowering W<strong>ork</strong>ers Through Community Contracting ................. 3015.4 Organising out of Poverty: Taxis in Rwanda ................................. 3065.5 Authority Systems: Land Rights ................................................. 3075.6 Gold Rush in Mongolia: from Herders to “Ninjas”........................ 3205.7 Land Sector Harmonisation, Alignment and Coordination<strong>for</strong> Poverty Reduction in Kenya ........................................................ 319Figures 5.1 Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor ................................................. 2385.2 Influences on Policy Implementation: Empowering <strong>the</strong> Poor ......... 2895.3 Conflict Implications of Public Policy ......................................... 3115.4 Road Map to <strong>the</strong> Implementation Cycle ...................................... 315Tables 5.1 Sample LEP Re<strong>for</strong>ms ............................................................... 2855.2 Illustrative Stakeholder Matrix ................................................... 2915.3 Political Administrative Syndromes ............................................ 3035.4 Skeleton Diagnostic Tool:Analyzing Influences on Policy Implementation ................................. 3135.5 Country Specific Implementation Road Map:Representative Summary Checklist .................................................. 317


5.6 Empowerment Domain 1: Access to Justice ................................ 3185.7 Empowerment Domain 2: Property Rights ................................... 3195.8 Empowerment Domain 3: Labour Rights ..................................... 3215.9 Empowerment Domain 4: Business Rights .................................. 3215.10 LEP Implementation Strategies and Indicative Activities ............ 3235.11 Pro-poor Policy Implementation Tools ....................................... 3305.12 A Framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> a Demand-led Assessment of Implementation ... 331


ChapterONEAccess to Justice and<strong>the</strong> Rule of <strong>Law</strong>1


1. IntroductionThe Commission on Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor (CLEP) emphasises re<strong>for</strong>ms to <strong>the</strong> law andjustice sector that will provide poor people with<strong>the</strong> institutional environment, protections, andincentives that <strong>the</strong>y need to realise <strong>the</strong>ir full capabilitiesand reap <strong>the</strong> maximum potential returnon <strong>the</strong>ir existing assets. This in turn requires legalprotection <strong>for</strong> physical assets (property rights),human capital (labour rights), and <strong>the</strong> ability toengage in profitable market transactions (entrepreneurialrights). Poor communities also requirebasic services that cannot be supplied efficientlyin <strong>the</strong> private market, such as essential utilities,a healthy environment, public security, and asocial safety net. The legal system must protectaccess to both private rights and public goods ifpoor people are to be able to escape poverty.Poor people tend to live in communities withscarce resources. The challenge <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> justicesystem, those who govern and <strong>the</strong>ir internationalpartners is <strong>for</strong>midable: How to turn <strong>the</strong> law intoan effective tool <strong>for</strong> those living in absolute poverty— people living with less than a dollar a day?The optimistic goal of our w<strong>ork</strong>ing group <strong>for</strong>Chapter 1 was to identify promising strategies <strong>for</strong>legally empowering poor people to have accessto justice. In <strong>the</strong> process, we investigated bestavailable practices and solicited suggestions duringa series of national consultations organised by<strong>the</strong> Commission (CLEP), and we reviewed evaluationstudies of access to justice programmesconducted by various NGOs. It was apparent thatacademic research had delivered many case studiesabout in<strong>for</strong>mal justice systems in developingcountries.In addition to <strong>the</strong> focus on practice, experienceand <strong>the</strong> variety of outcomes, we propose toconsider <strong>the</strong>ory. Although law and developmentis a recognised research topic (since <strong>the</strong> 1960s),<strong>the</strong>re is as yet no generally accepted framew<strong>ork</strong>our w<strong>ork</strong>ing group could use <strong>for</strong> analysing accessto justice issues. Many strands of research, however,from institutional economics to negotiation<strong>the</strong>ory and from legal anthropology to <strong>the</strong> analysisof market failure, can yield in<strong>for</strong>mation about <strong>the</strong>most promising strategies <strong>for</strong> providing access tojustice. <strong>Law</strong> and development, operating under<strong>the</strong> name of legal empowerment, is one particularstrand <strong>the</strong> Commission could usefully buildon (Golub and McQuay 2001; Golub 2003), and<strong>the</strong>re are o<strong>the</strong>rs using bottom-up perspectives (VanRooij 2007). More generally, bottom-up and empowermentapproaches have been part of <strong>the</strong> developmentagenda since <strong>the</strong> late 1990s (Narayan2005), and <strong>the</strong>y have now become building blocksof programmes such as <strong>the</strong> World Bank’s w<strong>ork</strong> inCommunity Driven Development and, more recently,its Justice <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor programme.In addition to issues of practice and <strong>the</strong>ory, wewill consider legal principles. It may be difficult2


to achieve access to justice <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor througha <strong>for</strong>mal justice system, but <strong>the</strong> ideals of <strong>the</strong> ruleof law are an indispensable part of <strong>the</strong> vision of<strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agenda. Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor requires a society governed by<strong>the</strong> rule of law. While <strong>the</strong> ‘rule of law’ has differentmeanings in different contexts, US Justice AnthonyKennedy (a Commissioner of <strong>the</strong> CLEP) hasdefined <strong>the</strong> rule of law as requiring fidelity to principlesregarding law being superior and binding,non-discriminating, respectful of people, givingpeople voice and <strong>the</strong>ir human rights, and effective(see Textbox 1 <strong>for</strong> his and o<strong>the</strong>r definitions).Ra<strong>the</strong>r than attempting a comprehensive surveyor a tailor-made <strong>the</strong>oretical framew<strong>ork</strong>, this chapterfocuses on varying aspects of <strong>the</strong> access tojustice issue. Section 2 addresses a widespreadand so far underappreciated problem: many poorpeople lack any sort of legal identity or <strong>for</strong>mallegal recognition, and as a result <strong>the</strong>y are completelyexcluded from <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal protections of<strong>the</strong> state legal system and as beneficiaries ofpublic goods and services. Section 3 turns to <strong>the</strong>basic challenge <strong>for</strong> our w<strong>ork</strong>ing group: How can<strong>the</strong> justness and fairness of what is delivered beimproved? How can <strong>the</strong> costs be reduced? Fourstrategies to improve access to justice are discussed.We start at <strong>the</strong> client end of <strong>the</strong> supplychain with facilitating self-help and education.Then we move on to <strong>the</strong> provision of legal services,<strong>the</strong> development of procedures that are bettersuited to legal needs and resources of <strong>the</strong> poor,and <strong>the</strong> potential of in<strong>for</strong>mal justice.Box 1 Rule of <strong>Law</strong> and JusticeThe rule of law (….) refers to a principle of governancein which all persons, institutions and entities,public and private, including <strong>the</strong> state itself, areaccountable to laws that are publicly promulgated,equally en<strong>for</strong>ced and independently adjudicated, andwhich are consistent with international human rightsnorms and standards. It requires, as well, measures toensure adherence to <strong>the</strong> principles of supremacy of law,equality be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong> law, accountability to <strong>the</strong> law, fairnessin <strong>the</strong> application of <strong>the</strong> law, separation of powers,participation in decision-making, legal certainty,avoidance of arbitrariness, and procedural and legaltransparency.(…)“justice” is an ideal of accountability and fairnessin <strong>the</strong> protection and vindication of rights and <strong>the</strong>prevention and punishment of wrongs. Justice impliesregard <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> rights of <strong>the</strong> accused, <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> interests ofvictims and <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> well-being of society at large. It isa concept rooted in all national cultures and traditionsand, while its administration usually implies <strong>for</strong>maljudicial mechanisms, traditional dispute resolutionmechanisms are equally relevant. The internationalcommunity has w<strong>ork</strong>ed to articulate collectively <strong>the</strong>substantive and procedural requirements <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> administrationof justice <strong>for</strong> more than half a century(Rule of <strong>Law</strong> and Transitional Justice in Conflict andPost-Conflict Societies Report of <strong>the</strong> Secretary-General;S/2004/616 of 23 August 2004).The <strong>Law</strong> is superior to, and thus binds, <strong>the</strong> governmentand all its officials.The <strong>Law</strong> affirms and protects <strong>the</strong> equality of all persons.By way of example only, <strong>the</strong> law may not dis-criminateagainst persons by reason of race, color, religion,or gender.The law must respect <strong>the</strong> dignity and preserve <strong>the</strong>human rights of all persons.The <strong>Law</strong> must establish and respect <strong>the</strong> constitutionalstructures necessary to secure a free and decent societyand to give all citizens a meaningful voice in <strong>for</strong>mulatingand enacting <strong>the</strong> rules that govern <strong>the</strong>m.The <strong>Law</strong> must devise and maintain systems to adviseall persons of <strong>the</strong>ir rights and just expectations, andto empower <strong>the</strong>m to seek redress <strong>for</strong> grievances andfulfilment of just expectations without fear of penalty orretaliation. (Kennedy 2007).3


Theoretical perspectives that in<strong>for</strong>m this analysisare reducing transaction costs, as well as remedyingmarket failure like imperfect in<strong>for</strong>mation.Section 4 addresses <strong>the</strong> related but distinct issueof access to justice in relation to <strong>the</strong> bureaucracyof public administration. It considers how <strong>the</strong>poor can get access to <strong>the</strong> complaint structuresof <strong>the</strong> state and <strong>the</strong> public administration. Conclusionsare drawn in a final fifth section.2. An Access to JusticeCornerstone: Legal Identity 1The Nature of <strong>the</strong> ProblemOne important basis of legal empowerment is ‘legalidentity’: <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal, legal recognition by <strong>the</strong>state that a person exists. In developed countries,citizens take this <strong>for</strong> granted. Whe<strong>the</strong>r through abirth certificate, national ID card, or o<strong>the</strong>r means,<strong>the</strong>y are empowered to own property, legally w<strong>ork</strong>,contract to buy and sell goods, receive governmentbenefits, vote, initiate a complaint through<strong>the</strong> channels of public administration, bring suitin a court of law, or avail <strong>the</strong>mselves of o<strong>the</strong>r legalprotections.But <strong>the</strong> situation in many developing countriesis much different. Weaknesses in <strong>the</strong> managementof birth registries, costly and time-consumingprocedures needed to register, and o<strong>the</strong>robstacles can make securing a legal identity achallenge. And a person without legal identityis denied a whole range of benefits essential <strong>for</strong>overcoming poverty. She may be unable to attendschool, obtain medical services, vote inelections, get a driver’s license, or open a bankaccount. Moreover, those who lack a <strong>for</strong>mal legalidentity are often unable to take advantage ofanti-poverty programmes specifically designed <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong>m. Those who lack a <strong>for</strong>mal identity may alsobe especially vulnerable to exploitative practices,including child labour and human trafficking.The importance of providing all people with <strong>for</strong>mallegal recognition has long been recognised.Indeed, <strong>the</strong> Universal Declaration of HumanRights announced over 50 years ago that, “<strong>Everyone</strong>has <strong>the</strong> right to recognition everywhere asa person be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong> law” (Art. 6). The UniversalDeclaration also affirmed <strong>the</strong> right of all people to‘nationality,’ meaning <strong>the</strong> right to be considered a4


citizen of some state (Art. 15). Subsequent globaland regional human rights treaties have reaffirmedand refined <strong>the</strong> basic human right to legalrecognition and nationality. 2 (It should be notedthat legal registration and citizenship, thoughrelated, are distinct issues. One can have uncertaincitizenship even in <strong>the</strong> presence of a validbirth registration. The primary focus of <strong>the</strong> currentdiscussion is <strong>the</strong> issue of registration, though<strong>the</strong> issue of citizenship is necessarily also part of<strong>the</strong> discussion, given <strong>the</strong> close linkages between<strong>the</strong> issues.)Despite this <strong>for</strong>mal recognition of a fundamentalindividual right to a <strong>for</strong>mally recognisedlegal identity, however, <strong>the</strong> lack of legalidentity remains a widespread problem. Althoughreliable systematic data is limited, <strong>the</strong> availableevidence suggests that <strong>the</strong> number of peoplewho lack a legal identity number in <strong>the</strong> tens ofmillions (UNICEF 2005). Those without legalidentity are disproportionately poor, and are oftenmembers of disadvantaged indigenous peoples oro<strong>the</strong>r ethnic minorities.In Latin America, <strong>for</strong> example, some estimatesput <strong>the</strong> number of “functionally undocumented”Bolivian citizens as high as two million or closeto one-third of <strong>the</strong> total population; in some partsof <strong>the</strong> country, over 90 percent of <strong>the</strong> populationlacks a valid <strong>for</strong>m of identification (Ardaya andSierra 2002). In Peru, approximately one millionPeruvian highlanders have no legal identity andno legal rights (Axworthy 2007). In several Argentinemunicipalities, some 15 percent of potentialbeneficiaries of an anti-poverty programme wereunable to participate due to <strong>the</strong> lack of a validnational ID card (IADB 2006). According toUNICEF (2005), roughly 23 million South Asianchildren — over 60 percent of all children bornin <strong>the</strong> region — are born but not registered eachyear. In Nepal, about four-fifths of all births areunregistered, which means that upwards of fourfifthsof Nepalese citizens may be denied lawfulaccess to education, employment opportunities,and <strong>the</strong> political process (Laczo 2003). Thingsare not much better in sub-Saharan Africa: overhalf of all children in this part of <strong>the</strong> world arenot registered, meaning that each year approximately15 million children are born without <strong>the</strong>means to access ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy orgovernment-provided social services. Worldwide,approximately 40 percent of children in developingcountries are not registered by <strong>the</strong>ir fifthbirthday, and in <strong>the</strong> least-developed countries,this number climbs to a shocking 71 percent(UNICEF 2005).It is <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e no exaggeration to describe <strong>the</strong>current situation as a worldwide governance crisis.Effective remediation of this crisis requiresboth a diagnosis of its causes and an assessmentof different strategies <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m.Addressing <strong>the</strong> Causes of <strong>the</strong> LegalIdentity Crisis: Incapacity, Exclusion,and AvoidanceAlthough no two countries are exactly alike, <strong>the</strong>legal identity crisis appears to have three primarycauses:• First, many countries lack an effective bureaucraticsystem <strong>for</strong> providing accessible,reliable, and low-cost registration services <strong>for</strong>all people who would like to <strong>for</strong>mally register<strong>the</strong>mselves with <strong>the</strong> state.• Second, in far too many countries <strong>the</strong> denialof legal identity is <strong>the</strong> result of a deliberateinterest in excluding certain groups from fullparticipation in <strong>the</strong> economy, polity, and publicsphere. Sometimes this exclusivity arisesbecause of reprehensible discriminatory animus.In o<strong>the</strong>r cases, such as those involving5


long-term migrant or refugee populations, <strong>the</strong>problem is more complex and delicate, and itmay implicate <strong>the</strong> policies of more than onestate. Despite <strong>the</strong>se differences, in all <strong>the</strong>secases people are deprived of <strong>the</strong>ir fundamentalentitlement to <strong>for</strong>mal legal recognition becauseof a political decision to exclude <strong>the</strong>m.• Third, some poor individuals may lack <strong>for</strong>mallegal registration because <strong>the</strong>y choosenot to take <strong>the</strong> steps necessary to acquireit. This avoidance may seem irrational given<strong>the</strong> adverse consequences of lacking a legalidentity. Sometimes this avoidance behaviourmay arise because of an ingrained distrust ofstate authorities. But often avoidance of stateauthority, and <strong>for</strong>mal registration in particular,may be entirely rational. Formal legal registrationmay also make one more vulnerable totaxation, conscription, or various <strong>for</strong>ms of undesirablestate monitoring. Thus, governmentpolicy may lead to <strong>the</strong> legal exclusion of poordisadvantaged communities not only becauseof a lack of capacity or a deliberate policy ofexclusion, but also because o<strong>the</strong>r governmentpolicies create excessive disincentives to registration.These three categories are not mutually exclusive,nor are <strong>the</strong> boundaries between <strong>the</strong>m alwayssharp. For instance, <strong>the</strong> capacity of <strong>the</strong> bureaucracyto register births may remain weak becausepowerful political interests have an incentive notto fix <strong>the</strong> problems. This “passive” discriminationis partly an issue of bureaucratic incapacity andpartly an issue of deliberate exclusion. None<strong>the</strong>less,this crude tripartite scheme is usefulbecause it underscores <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> legalidentity problem has a diverse set of possiblecauses, and proposed solutions must <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>ebe tailored to <strong>the</strong> particular situation. Proposedre<strong>for</strong>ms to <strong>the</strong> registration system may be of limiteduse when exclusion results from deliberatepolicy choices. Likewise, high-level political pressureand <strong>the</strong> entrenchment of non-discriminationnorms do not guarantee success when <strong>the</strong> problemis low bureaucratic capacity. Let us consider<strong>the</strong> three primary sources of <strong>the</strong> legal identitycrisis and what might be done about <strong>the</strong>m.Streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong> Capacity of <strong>the</strong> RegistrationSystemMany government-run civil registration systemsimpose particularly onerous burdens on poorpeople. Registration systems often require registrantsto pay a fee; many will not waive this feeeven <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> indigent. Some registration systemsalso require that <strong>the</strong> registrant appear in personat a registration office that may be located a significantdistance from a prospective registrant’sresidence. Both travel costs and <strong>the</strong> opportunitycosts of <strong>the</strong> prospective registrant’s time mayweigh heavily against registration, especially <strong>for</strong>poor people in remote areas with limited disposableincome. And, of course, petty corruption maysubstantially raise <strong>the</strong> costs of <strong>for</strong>mal registration,as <strong>the</strong> prospective registrant may have to paybribes as well as official registration fees. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore,<strong>the</strong> bureaucratic registration processitself is often complicated and time-consuming,presenting applicants with a labyrinthine array of<strong>for</strong>ms and procedural requirements, and <strong>the</strong> bureaucraticpersonnel who run many national registrationsystems are often insufficient and poorlytrained (Barendrecht and van Nispen 2007).Registration offices may also lack <strong>the</strong> most basicresources. For example, surveys of woman in LatinAmerica reveal that approximately 10 percentof women did not register <strong>the</strong>ir children because<strong>the</strong> local registration office lacked <strong>the</strong> proper stationary(IADB 2006).A natural first step in redressing <strong>the</strong> legal iden-6


tity crisis is to reduce <strong>the</strong> financial and physicalbarriers to access that disproportionately burdenpoor and rural communities. With respect to<strong>the</strong> financial barriers, an obvious re<strong>for</strong>m is <strong>the</strong>elimination of fees <strong>for</strong> registration and acquisitionof a first copy of <strong>the</strong> necessary identificationdocuments. The usual arguments <strong>for</strong> user fees <strong>for</strong>government services do not apply <strong>for</strong> legal registration:legal identity is not a scarce resource thata government might legitimately want to ration,nor is registration a service that people have anincentive to “over-consume” if <strong>the</strong>y do not bear<strong>the</strong> costs of providing <strong>the</strong> service. Also, most of<strong>the</strong> cost of a registration programme is <strong>the</strong> fixedcost of creating and maintaining <strong>the</strong> necessarybureaucratic infrastructure; <strong>the</strong> variable cost associatedwith <strong>the</strong> number of registration requestsis likely to be relatively small. As between eliminatingregistration fees altoge<strong>the</strong>r and providinga waiver <strong>for</strong> poor individuals, <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mer approachis generally preferable as it eliminates <strong>the</strong> administrativecosts associated with determiningwho is eligible <strong>for</strong> a waiver. The costs of operatingregistration programmes, in most cases, shouldbe met through lump-sum budget allocationsmade out of general public revenues ra<strong>the</strong>r thanthrough user fees.In addition to eliminating fees, prospective registrantsshould, where possible, be given multipleavenues through which <strong>the</strong>y can register <strong>the</strong>iridentities, ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>for</strong>cing <strong>the</strong>m to rely on asingle bureaucratic provider of registration services.This redundancy might admittedly entailsome administrative costs, but it would yield twosignificant benefits. First, this system would alloweach individual to select <strong>the</strong> method that is easiestand cheapest <strong>for</strong> her. Second, having multipleproviders of registration services reduces <strong>the</strong> opportunities<strong>for</strong> corruption, abuse, and delay, becauseprospective registrants will avoid a registrationprovider that has a bad reputation (Shleiferand Vishney 1993). As a rough-and-ready ruleof thumb, every individual should always have atleast two realistic, viable options <strong>for</strong> registeringherself or her child. Of course, right now manypeople have zero realistic, viable options, so goingfrom zero to one would have to be counted animprovement, but two or more would be better.In communities that have <strong>the</strong> requisite in<strong>for</strong>mationtechnology infrastructure, it might also bepossible <strong>for</strong> private firms, civil society organisations,governments, or some combination of allthree to set up offices where people can register<strong>the</strong>mselves using a simple interactive computersystem, perhaps with assistance from on-sitetechnical staff (Barendrecht and van Nispen2007). This alternative may not be realistic <strong>for</strong>all poor communities, but where it is feasible, itmay be a better alternative to relying on paper<strong>for</strong>ms and in-person interaction with governmentbureaucrats. Employing such a strategy, where itis feasible, may free up more resources that can<strong>the</strong>n be targeted at o<strong>the</strong>r communities.The difficulty of reaching poor communities, especiallydispersed rural communities, remains achallenge. There are several strategies that governmentsand interested organisations might use toimprove <strong>the</strong> outreach and efficacy of registrationef<strong>for</strong>ts. One strategy is to simplify <strong>the</strong> registrationprocess and to improve training of government officialsand o<strong>the</strong>rs. Ano<strong>the</strong>r technique that has shownpromise involves <strong>the</strong> wide distribution of semiportableregistration kits. In <strong>the</strong> Democratic Republicof Congo, <strong>for</strong> example, UNDP and <strong>the</strong> UnitedNations Mission to Congo succeeded in registeringapproximately 25.7 million Congolese in 2006 inadvance of <strong>the</strong> national elections. They did this byusing planes, boats, trucks, canoes, and carts todistribute registration kits, each of which containeda laptop computer, fingerprinting materials, and a7


digital camera that could be used to issue photoID cards on <strong>the</strong> spot (Paldi 2006). The Cambodiangovernment used an even more aggressive approachto ‘mobile registration’: following changes to <strong>the</strong>Cambodian Civil Code that made birth registrationmandatory, mobile registration teams — run bynon-governmental organisations but with <strong>the</strong> government’sblessing — have been going door-to-doorto deliver free birth registrations to people’s homessince 2004. The results have been dramatic: over<strong>the</strong> course of only a few years, <strong>the</strong> number of registeredCambodian citizens increased from 5 percentto 85 percent (Damazo 2006). A UNICEF-backedprogramme in Bangladesh has employed a similarstrategy, sending trained registrars house-to-house,with similar results: in <strong>the</strong> ten years since this programmebegan, over 12 million births have been<strong>for</strong>mally registered (UNICEF 2006).Ano<strong>the</strong>r potentially valuable approach to improvingregistration ef<strong>for</strong>ts is to ‘bundle’ registrationwith o<strong>the</strong>r service delivery programmes. For example,many countries have, or are considering,extensive vaccination programmes <strong>for</strong> children inpoor communities. It may often be relatively easy<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> health w<strong>ork</strong>er providing <strong>the</strong> vaccination toregister each child she vaccinates (ADB 2005).This approach, used successfully in Bangladesh,is more cost effective than financing a separateregistration campaign alongside <strong>the</strong> vaccinationcampaign <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> same population (UNICEF2006). In addition, it is conceivable that <strong>the</strong>mo<strong>the</strong>r, and even <strong>the</strong> extended family members,can be registered at <strong>the</strong> same time without muchextra ef<strong>for</strong>t, thus profiting from a fitting chainregistration service. Similarly, some poor women— sadly, not nearly enough — receive some <strong>for</strong>mof prenatal care, and some have <strong>the</strong> assistanceof a health care professional at delivery. Whilewomen receiving prenatal and delivery care arealready more likely to register <strong>the</strong>ir children, empoweringhealth providers to register newbornsmight substantially improve registration ef<strong>for</strong>ts.For example, a pilot programme in large publichospitals in South Africa was successful in registeringlarge numbers of poor children (UNICEF2003). Primary school registration at enrolmenttime is yet ano<strong>the</strong>r opportunity <strong>for</strong> registeringchildren who might o<strong>the</strong>rwise lack a legal identityif <strong>the</strong>y had not have been registered at birth.An alternative strategy that might be effective,provided that incentives are well targeted, is outsourcing<strong>the</strong> partial or entire registration processto local stores, banks, and o<strong>the</strong>r places were peopleengage in economic activities. Similarly, somepoor women — though, sadly, not nearly enough— receive some <strong>for</strong>m of prenatal care, and somehave <strong>the</strong> assistance of a health care professionalat delivery. While women who receive prenataland delivery care are already more likely to register<strong>the</strong>ir children, empowering <strong>the</strong>se healthproviders to register newborns might substantiallyimprove registration ef<strong>for</strong>ts.Ano<strong>the</strong>r sort of ‘bundling’ strategy might link<strong>for</strong>mal legal registration with traditional culturalpractices such as naming ceremonies (ADB2005). Just as religious leaders are often empoweredto officiate at weddings and legally validatemarriages, so, too, can religious or communityleaders officiating at childbirth rituals be empoweredby <strong>the</strong> state to register children. This approachhas <strong>the</strong> advantage of making registrationseem less like an alien <strong>for</strong>mality imposed by <strong>the</strong>state and more like an integral part of familiarcultural traditions. A related observation is thatlocal chiefs or community leaders can often serveas a valuable liaison between registration authoritiesand poor communities. The local chief canboth provide in<strong>for</strong>mation to <strong>the</strong> community anddeal with <strong>the</strong> state authorities.8


Thus, reaching out to local cultural and religiousleaders, and empowering <strong>the</strong>m to <strong>for</strong>mally registerindividuals, may be a more viable strategythan attempting to expand <strong>the</strong> state registrationbureaucracy. At <strong>the</strong> same time, care must betaken not to grant local elites a monopoly on <strong>the</strong>provision of <strong>for</strong>mal legal identity. A useful rule ofthumb regarding registration is that every individualshould always have at least two realistic,viable options.Reducing Political Opposition to Full RegistrationFee waivers, redundancy, outreach, and bundlingmay all help redress non-registration that arisesbecause of a lack of bureaucratic capacity, butall too often <strong>the</strong> denial of a legal identity resultsfrom an explicit or tacit political decisionto exclude certain segments of <strong>the</strong> populationfrom full and equal participation. This problemis especially obvious in <strong>the</strong> case of groups thathave been denied citizenship on grounds of <strong>the</strong>irethnicity or <strong>the</strong>ir status as refugees or migrants.Examples of groups that have no <strong>for</strong>mal citizenshiprights, or very limited ‘second class’ citizenshiprights, include <strong>the</strong> Russians in Estoniaand Latvia, <strong>the</strong> Kurds in Syria, <strong>the</strong> Palestiniansthroughout <strong>the</strong> Middle East, <strong>the</strong> Rohingyas inMyanmar and Bangladesh, <strong>the</strong> Lhotshampas andBihari in Bangladesh, <strong>the</strong> Banyarwanda in Congo,and <strong>the</strong> Nubians in Kenya. 3Even in cases that do not involve overt deprivationof citizenship, political considerationsmay influence government decisions toleave barriers to <strong>for</strong>mal registration in place. Forexample, in <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong> Peruvian highlanders,<strong>for</strong>mal registration could potentially drawlarge numbers of poor indigenous Peruvians into<strong>the</strong> political process, posing a potential threatto <strong>the</strong> incumbent political elites. Additionally,precisely because <strong>the</strong> lack of legal identity mayblock access to government social services,politicians may recognise that extensive legalregistration of <strong>the</strong> poor may be very expensive,because registration would put greater demandson <strong>the</strong> public treasury.When legal exclusion derives from a lack of politicalinterest in providing legal identity — or,worse, from an affirmative political desire to denylegal identity — one strategy that is sometimeseffective is to increase <strong>the</strong> international profileof a problem and to identify those countries thatdeprive <strong>the</strong>ir residents of an adequate legal identityon a discriminatory basis. Such ‘naming andshaming’ approaches may not be effective againstcountries where <strong>the</strong> interest in discriminatoryexclusion is especially strong or where <strong>the</strong> interestin international reputation is especially weak,but in some cases greater international attentionto <strong>the</strong> issue may help effect a shift in policy. Forexample, international pressure appears to haveinfluenced <strong>the</strong> Thai government’s stance toward<strong>the</strong> registration of <strong>the</strong> approximately 2.5 millionpeople living in nor<strong>the</strong>rn Thailand, most of <strong>the</strong>mmembers of various Hill Tribes, who lack officialregistration documents and who consequently aredenied citizenship (Lynch 2005, Lin 2006). Inaddition to country and situation-specific internationalpressure, it would be useful if an internationalorganisation, such as UNICEF, UNESCO, orsome prominent NGO, regularly ranked countrieswith regard to <strong>the</strong>ir policies on registration, citizenship,and legal identity. This sort of publicitybasedapproach should be carried out in conjunctionwith more sustained ef<strong>for</strong>ts to ga<strong>the</strong>r reliabledata on <strong>the</strong> scope of <strong>the</strong> legal identity problem.However, any international attempt to address<strong>the</strong> legal identity issue must be sensitive to legitimatestate interests in restricting citizenshiprights, regulating immigration, addressing ongoinginternational disputes, and combating voting9


or social services fraud. Thus, although greaterinternational attention and <strong>the</strong> use of ‘namingand shaming’ approaches may be useful, <strong>the</strong> internationalcommunity must take care to developits evaluations and prescriptions through a dialoguewith relevant stakeholders.Ano<strong>the</strong>r possible approach to combating politicallymotivated legal exclusions is to bring legalclaims be<strong>for</strong>e international human rights tribunals.The track record of this strategy is mixed,however: while international human rightslitigation has sometimes succeeded in raisingawareness, <strong>the</strong> tribunal decisions <strong>the</strong>mselveshave typically not been en<strong>for</strong>ced effectively.While international human rights litigation mayhave a place in <strong>the</strong> broader campaign to address<strong>the</strong> legal identity crisis, it would be a mistaketo presume that politically-motivated exclusioncan be cured by litigation. Political problemsdemand a political solution, and human rightslitigation is useful only if it is part of a broaderpolitical strategy.More generally, <strong>the</strong> crisis of politically-motivatedlegal exclusion highlights <strong>the</strong> need to increase<strong>the</strong> relevance and effectiveness of <strong>the</strong> variousinternational covenants and declarations thatestablish <strong>the</strong> basic human rights to legal identityand nationality. Part of <strong>the</strong> problem mightbe attributable to a failure of national and internationalpolitical will to make <strong>the</strong> en<strong>for</strong>cementof <strong>the</strong>se fundamental rights a priority. Ano<strong>the</strong>rproblem might be that most of <strong>the</strong> existing humanrights conventions and protocols discussgeneral goals or end-states, but do not establishconcrete benchmarks or standards by which tojudge compliance ef<strong>for</strong>ts. It may <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e beworth considering if existing international humanrights instruments relating to legal identityshould be supplemented with clear internationalstandards establishing markers by which nationalactions on legal identity can be evaluated.An alternative or complement to publicinternational action might be greater ef<strong>for</strong>ts by<strong>the</strong> donor, academic, and NGO communities toestablish institutes and foundations dedicated toraising <strong>the</strong> profile of <strong>the</strong> legal identity issue andmonitoring state compliance with <strong>the</strong> obligationto ensure that all people have proof of nationalityand are recognised as people in <strong>the</strong> eyes of<strong>the</strong> law.Providing In<strong>for</strong>mation and Creating Incentives toRegisterEven when opportunities to register one’s legalidentity are available, many of <strong>the</strong> poor may stillfail to take advantage of <strong>the</strong>se opportunities. Onereason may be because poor people do not knowabout <strong>for</strong>mal registration, or <strong>the</strong>y do not understand<strong>the</strong> benefits of a <strong>for</strong>mal legal identity. Ano<strong>the</strong>rreason may be that <strong>the</strong> poor are suspiciousof <strong>the</strong> state and its agents, and this warinessleads <strong>the</strong>m to avoid <strong>for</strong>mal registration even whenit would be in <strong>the</strong>ir interests. Yet a third possibilityis <strong>the</strong>ir rational calculation that <strong>the</strong> expectedcosts of <strong>for</strong>mal registration outweigh <strong>the</strong> benefits.When ignorance or wariness of <strong>the</strong> state are <strong>the</strong>major obstacles, one method of redress may be torely on culturally familiar and reliable intermediariesto convey in<strong>for</strong>mation about registration andto assist with <strong>the</strong> registration process. Bundlingof registration services toge<strong>the</strong>r with o<strong>the</strong>r governmentor NGO services or with traditional ritualsand practices would be consistent with this approach.More generally, many successful registrationef<strong>for</strong>ts have relied on paralegals, NGOs andlaypeople to assist poor individuals and communitiesin completing <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal registrationprocedure.For example, <strong>the</strong> Egyptian Centre <strong>for</strong> Women’sRights and o<strong>the</strong>r Egyptian civil society organi-10


sations, with <strong>the</strong> cooperation of <strong>the</strong> Egyptiangovernment and some financial support from <strong>the</strong>World Bank, have helped thousands of womenobtain legal identity cards (World Bank 2007). AUNICEF-backed project in Bangladesh run by localNGOs used a similar approach, with similarlyencouraging results (UNICEF 2006). Relianceon NGOs and community-based organisations isparticularly valuable in registering groups (suchas women and traditionally disadvantaged ethnicminorities), which may be especially wary of<strong>the</strong> state bureaucracy. In addition, <strong>the</strong>re is someevidence that improvements in women’s healthand education will also improve birth registration.For example, studies in Latin America havefound that <strong>the</strong> likelihood a child will be registeredis positively correlated with <strong>the</strong> mo<strong>the</strong>r’s ageand education (UNICEF 2005). This and relatedfindings suggest that programmes designed toeducate and empower poor women, in additionto <strong>the</strong>ir numerous o<strong>the</strong>r benefits, may also helpredress <strong>the</strong> legal identity crisis.which case, institutional re<strong>for</strong>ms and registrationdrives may not be helpful; <strong>the</strong>y may evenbe counter-productive if <strong>the</strong>y coerce or persuadepoor people into registration that is ultimatelyagainst <strong>the</strong>ir own interests.Major difficulties arise when poor people avoid<strong>for</strong>mal registration <strong>for</strong> rational reasons — <strong>for</strong>example, avoiding taxation, conscription, orvulnerability to a variety of state abuses. Ultimately,expanding access to legal identity inthis situation will require ei<strong>the</strong>r mitigating <strong>the</strong>adverse consequences of <strong>for</strong>mal registration orincreasing <strong>the</strong> benefits associated with <strong>for</strong>malregistration, both of which might entail extensivechanges to substantive law or political institutions.While this barrier to change defies cleargeneral solutions, it is none<strong>the</strong>less important torecognise it as a possibility. Well-meaning observersare sometimes too quick to assume that<strong>the</strong> poor are ei<strong>the</strong>r ignorant or irrational when<strong>the</strong>y fail to take advantage of an apparentlyavailable government service. It may be thatthis avoidance is both in<strong>for</strong>med and rational, in11


3. Strategies to CreateAf<strong>for</strong>dable, Inclusive andFair JusticeThe Nature of <strong>the</strong> ProblemThe Social Realities of Access to JusticeThe poor <strong>the</strong>mselves know best when <strong>the</strong>y needjustice most. Legal needs surveys and case studiesdisplay a recurring pattern of situations inwhich poor people have needs or grievances thatare translated into justifiable claims invokingsubstantive rights (Michelson 2007; UNDP Indonesia2007). First, and <strong>for</strong>emost, <strong>the</strong>y need personalsecurity and guarantees that <strong>the</strong>ir physicalintegrity is not threatened. Worries about personaland physical safety and fear that property or o<strong>the</strong>rassets will be taken by <strong>for</strong>ce diminish <strong>the</strong> humanresources people have left <strong>for</strong> seizing opportunities.This also requires legal protection <strong>for</strong> physicalassets (property rights), human capital (labourrights), and <strong>the</strong> ability to engage in profitablemarket transactions (entrepreneurial rights). Poorcommunities also require basic services that cannotbe supplied efficiently in <strong>the</strong> private market,such as essential utilities, a healthy environment,public security, and a social safety net. The legalsystem must protect access to both private rightsand public goods and services if poor people areto be able to escape poverty. Protection of <strong>the</strong>irproperty not only requires effective registration,transparent and accountable land tenure systems,but also protection against expropriation and proceduresand accessible en<strong>for</strong>cement mechanismsthat resolve conflicts (see Chapter 2). Similarly,<strong>the</strong>ir interests as employees and as entrepreneursshould be recognised <strong>for</strong>mally, as well as protectedagainst attempts of o<strong>the</strong>rs to take advantage of<strong>the</strong>ir ef<strong>for</strong>ts (see Chapters 3 and 4).Surveys consistently show that <strong>the</strong> needs ofindividuals <strong>for</strong> legal interventions are concentratedaround <strong>the</strong> major transitions or changesin personal status in a lifetime. A likely reason<strong>for</strong> this is that property and o<strong>the</strong>r assets oftenaccrue within a relationship. This is especiallytrue <strong>for</strong> poor people. Their homes usually belongto families and kinships. They make use of <strong>the</strong>irarable land where <strong>the</strong> different members are designateddifferent tasks, roles and rights, whilst<strong>for</strong>mal officially recognised ownership is uncleareven though a clear in<strong>for</strong>mal regime may exist.They w<strong>ork</strong> in businesses as employees, but alsoas spouse, as a nephew, or as business partner.Communities jointly own pastures, share water,and use <strong>the</strong> same fishing grounds. These closerelationships are powerful tools <strong>for</strong> value creation,but <strong>the</strong>y also build on inter-dependent relations.The partners are tied to each o<strong>the</strong>r by specificinvestments, which will be lost if <strong>the</strong>y leave <strong>the</strong>relationship (Williamson 1985). And often <strong>the</strong>poorest person will have more to loose: tenantsand employees tend to invest more in this specificpiece of land or in <strong>the</strong> business, than <strong>the</strong>landlord or <strong>the</strong> employer invests in <strong>the</strong>ir person.Women often invest more time and ef<strong>for</strong>t in <strong>the</strong>family and its assets than <strong>the</strong>ir husbands. Thatmakes it difficult to leave <strong>the</strong> relationship, andmakes <strong>the</strong>m vulnerable to exploitation.The <strong>for</strong>mal (modern) legal system, with its focuson <strong>the</strong> individual and not on a more or lessstrongly defined collective entity, which is alsomirrored in how ownership is construed, oftendiscriminates against poor people or excludes<strong>the</strong>m de facto. In some societies, property thatdoes not clearly belong to an individual will beregarded as state property (see Chapter 2). Theassumption that contracts are <strong>the</strong> only meansthat allocate residual ownership to one of <strong>the</strong>partners in <strong>the</strong> relationship equally w<strong>ork</strong>s against12


<strong>the</strong> poor. Usually, <strong>the</strong>y do not <strong>for</strong>mally regulate<strong>the</strong>ir relationships. Even in developed countries,marriages, land use arrangements, and <strong>the</strong> relationshipsaround small businesses are often notdealt with in contracts, out of convenience, mutualtrust or because it is impossible to <strong>for</strong>eseeevery contingency.Thus, <strong>the</strong> most serious legal problems that<strong>the</strong> poor report in legal needs surveys revolvearound transitions in <strong>the</strong>se relationships. Deathof <strong>the</strong> head of <strong>the</strong> family, divorce, termination ofland use relationships, termination of employment,leaving a community (selling property), changesin business relationships, and expropriation <strong>for</strong>property development are <strong>the</strong> most common transitions.These transitions do not only create problemsof division of property, but also do so in asetting that is likely to lead to conflict. This is particularlytrue in areas with scarce natural resourcesand high population growth where poor familiescannot create sufficient extra value between transitionsto <strong>the</strong> next generation to make up <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>growth in numbers of mouths that have to be fed.In post conflict zones, and in areas struck by naturaldisaster, dislocated persons need to find propertywhere <strong>the</strong>y can rebuild <strong>the</strong>ir lives. The claimsof those returning home create extra transitionproblems and thus legal needs.The paths to justice available to <strong>the</strong> poor in orderto cope with <strong>the</strong>se problems and <strong>for</strong> accessing<strong>the</strong>ir rights often develop spontaneously. Communitiestend to organise social structures that dealwith conflict. Within days from <strong>the</strong> setting upof a refugee camp, <strong>the</strong> inhabitants create socialnorms and start addressing certain individualswith <strong>the</strong>ir grievances. Where a <strong>for</strong>mal registrationsystem is lacking, some person may start collectingin<strong>for</strong>mation about who owns which pieceof land and make <strong>the</strong>se data available to o<strong>the</strong>rs(see Chapter 2). Sometimes <strong>the</strong>se structures willmirror structures from <strong>the</strong>ir home areas becausewhole communities have been moved to <strong>the</strong>same locations. Or such structures are of a morepractical nature <strong>the</strong>n reflecting <strong>for</strong>mal or in<strong>for</strong>malprinciples of justice or customary normative systems.Whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> disadvantaged can use <strong>the</strong>msuccessfully to deal with <strong>the</strong>ir problems is variableand depends on access to resources, powerrelations and o<strong>the</strong>r factors. Ano<strong>the</strong>r option <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor is often present in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of religiousnorms and faith based dispute resolution mechanisms.The scope of <strong>the</strong>se mechanisms may belimited, however, to family issues and crime.They are less likely to extend to property rights,employment problems, and <strong>the</strong> issues related tosetting up businesses on which <strong>the</strong> Commissionon Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor focuses.In some communities, in<strong>for</strong>mal dispute resolutionmechanisms exist. A recent survey of in<strong>for</strong>maljustice systems identified <strong>the</strong> following commoncharacteristics of <strong>the</strong>se systems (Wojkowska2006). The problem is viewed as relating to <strong>the</strong>whole community as a group — <strong>the</strong>re is strongconsideration <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> collective interests at stakein disputes. Decisions are based on a process ofconsultation. There is an emphasis on reconciliationand restoring social harmony. Arbitratorsare appointed from within <strong>the</strong> community on <strong>the</strong>basis of status or lineage. There is often a highdegree of public participation. Rules of evidenceand procedure are flexible and no professionallegal representation is needed. The process is voluntary,although <strong>the</strong>re is frequently a lot of pressureinternally in <strong>the</strong> family or o<strong>the</strong>r groups on<strong>the</strong> ‘victim’ to be part of <strong>the</strong> process. The decisionis based on consensus, providing a high levelof acceptance and legitimacy. There are no cleardistinctions between criminal and civil cases,and between in<strong>for</strong>mal justice systems and localgovernance structures. En<strong>for</strong>cement of decisions13


is secured through social pressure or more organisedstructures invoked to ensure that parties to<strong>the</strong> conflict abide by <strong>the</strong> common decision.Because <strong>the</strong>se systems have been studiedmore intensively than <strong>the</strong> loose spontaneousordering that has been discussed above, more isknown about <strong>the</strong>ir weaknesses. These often w<strong>ork</strong>against <strong>the</strong> poor. In<strong>for</strong>mal systems tend to rein<strong>for</strong>ceexisting power structures. Because <strong>the</strong>y arebased on consensus, women and disadvantagedgroups may not be assisted to overcome differencesin power levels. Mediated settlements canonly reflect “what <strong>the</strong> stronger is willing to concedeand <strong>the</strong> weaker can successfully demand.”(Wojkowska 2006). And sometimes local normssuggest solutions that are clearly against <strong>the</strong> interestsof <strong>the</strong> weakest (<strong>the</strong>y are regularly all poor).For those living on less than $1 a day, <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mallegal system is often out of reach. As we haveseen, fees <strong>for</strong> birth registration can already be unaf<strong>for</strong>dable,and a court action to protect propertyrights or to en<strong>for</strong>ce a contract with a tenant is outof <strong>the</strong> question. The only dealings <strong>the</strong> poor mayhave with <strong>the</strong> official justice system may be asdefendants in criminal cases, in which <strong>the</strong>y willnormally have to cope without legal representation.They may suffer from bureaucratic proceduresand red tape (see Chapters 2, 3 and 4), or frompolice abuse. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, if <strong>the</strong> poor livein a country that has a functioning legal system,<strong>the</strong> influence of <strong>for</strong>mal legal rules and <strong>the</strong> threatof intervention by neutral courts, even if just aremote possibility, should not be underestimated(Kauffmann 2003).The actual situation from which processes improvingaccess to justice have to start can be summarisedas follows. The poor have legal grievancesand are even more likely to have such grievances,because of <strong>the</strong> scarcity in which <strong>the</strong>y live andbecause <strong>the</strong>y are more likely to be dependent ono<strong>the</strong>rs that are more powerful. They may havesome options to access <strong>the</strong>ir rights, throughspontaneous arrangements, through faith-basedsystems, through in<strong>for</strong>mal justice, or through <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mal legal system. But through <strong>the</strong>se options,taken jointly, <strong>the</strong>y are unlikely to obtain fair andjust outcomes against reasonable cost.Starting with <strong>the</strong> legal needs of <strong>the</strong> poor is essentialin a legal empowerment approach. Suchan analysis can clarify which elements of <strong>the</strong> ruleof law are particularly important <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor andto which neutral interventions <strong>the</strong>y need access.Targeting <strong>the</strong> most common legal needs can helpto make legal institutions more responsive. Attemptsto improve access to justice are less likelyto succeed if <strong>the</strong>y aim at access to criminal andcivil justice in <strong>the</strong> abstract. Justice is costly toprovide and priority setting is essential. Table 1highlights some likely priorities, and shows inwhich parts of this chapter <strong>the</strong>se are discussed.It takes <strong>the</strong> perspective of individuals needinglaw to protect <strong>the</strong>m and to solve <strong>the</strong>ir disputes,ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> perspective of <strong>the</strong> lawyer who appliesrules. Which norms do poor people need toknow and to apply, and which interventions canhelp <strong>the</strong>m?Seen from this side, many norms (like <strong>the</strong> onesprotecting property against <strong>the</strong>ft, and life againstmurder) are self-evident, whilst o<strong>the</strong>r norms mayyet need to be <strong>for</strong>med, or interpreted to becomeeasily applicable (such as <strong>the</strong> ones on division orcompensation in property disputes or on terminationof an employment contract). Likewise, <strong>the</strong>needs <strong>for</strong> interventions may be different. Seenfrom <strong>the</strong> perspective of <strong>the</strong> poor, criminal actsshould perhaps primarily be deterred, problems inongoing relationships should primarily be settledin a fair and just manner, <strong>for</strong> commercial transactionssimple en<strong>for</strong>cement of debts may be <strong>the</strong>14


Table 1 Needs <strong>for</strong> Norms and InterventionsPersonal security and property protection> Mainly criminal law, notcovered in this chapterIdentifi cation of person, property,business (registration) >See Section 2 of this chapterIssues within long term relationshipsin which <strong>the</strong> poor invest (entrepreneurial,family, land-use, employment,community) >Section 3Market transactions (debt, credit,consumer) > Section 3Protection against unfairgovernment interference (police,detention, o<strong>the</strong>r) >Section 4Problems arising out of failure ofgovernment to per<strong>for</strong>m positiveduties > Section 4NormsResponsibility to protectRespect <strong>for</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs’ human rightsRules that deal with standard complicationsefficientlyDefault rules <strong>for</strong> fair treatment duringrelationshipRules of thumb <strong>for</strong> division of assets atterminationRules regarding reasonable qualityexpectationsSimplifi ed contractual regimesRegulation of government conductRespect <strong>for</strong> human rightsNorms relating to positive dutiesIntervention capacityGeneral prevention strategiesRetributive/restorative/criminaljustice <strong>for</strong> most serious crimesRegistration capacity that serves <strong>the</strong>entire populationA setting that facilitates settlement,with:A credible threat of a neutral intervention(settlement in <strong>the</strong> shadow of <strong>the</strong> law)Self-en<strong>for</strong>cement through reputationmechanismsEn<strong>for</strong>cement of simple contractsComplaint procedures with independenten<strong>for</strong>cementResponsive governmentComplaint procedurespriority, and complaints against government mayhave to be used primarily as a tool <strong>for</strong> creatingmore responsive government. But any strategy toimprove access to justice should start from a thoroughanalysis of <strong>the</strong> particular needs in <strong>the</strong> localsituation, as well as an inquiry into <strong>the</strong> way <strong>the</strong>local institutions already fulfil <strong>the</strong>m.An analysis like this not only shows what <strong>the</strong> ruleof law and access to justice look like from <strong>the</strong>perspective of <strong>the</strong> poor. It also makes clear that<strong>the</strong>ir demands <strong>for</strong> justice are not unlimited orunrealistic. The poor need some norms in particularto protect <strong>the</strong>m and to give <strong>the</strong>m opportunities.They do not need a court or lawyers <strong>for</strong> everyproblem that <strong>the</strong>y have in relation to o<strong>the</strong>r people,but in some situations <strong>the</strong>y are vulnerable.In relationships in which <strong>the</strong>y are dependent ono<strong>the</strong>rs, <strong>the</strong>y need a credible threat of an interventionby a neutral and trustworthy person. Similarly,<strong>the</strong>ir human rights and <strong>the</strong>ir contractualrights should be backed up by <strong>the</strong> possibility ofen<strong>for</strong>cement. Like o<strong>the</strong>r people, <strong>the</strong> poor tend tosettle <strong>the</strong>ir problems <strong>the</strong>mselves. But like peoplewho live under a more effective legal system, <strong>the</strong>yneed <strong>the</strong> shadow of law to get access to fair andjust settlements of <strong>the</strong>ir differences.Increasing Quality and Reducing TransactionCostsThe observation that poor people have unmetlegal needs does not, however, adequately diagnose<strong>the</strong> problem to be solved, nor does it provide15


sufficient guidance as to <strong>the</strong> best solutions. Thereason <strong>for</strong> this is three-fold. First, access to legalservices — and, <strong>for</strong> that matter, access to justice— is not valuable in and of itself. The legal systemis a means <strong>for</strong> improving social welfare andsocial justice. Justice services are valuable insofaras <strong>the</strong>y advance those underlying goals. Second,justice services are a scarce and costly resource,and like any scarce resource, <strong>the</strong>y must be producedand allocated efficiently. Third, while poorpeople consume fewer justice services than isoptimal from a social welfare perspective, this istrue of most goods and services that <strong>the</strong> poor wantto consume. Poor people have unmet legal needs,but <strong>the</strong>y also have unmet needs <strong>for</strong> food, clothing,shelter, land, medical care, transportation, credit,leisure time, and virtually every o<strong>the</strong>r scarce resource.<strong>Everyone</strong> who advocates spending socialresources on providing justice services to <strong>the</strong> poorshould <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e be required to explain why accessto justice should be a priority.As a thought experiment, it is instructive to considerwhe<strong>the</strong>r it would not be better simply totake <strong>the</strong> amount spent on an access to justiceprogramme and give it directly to poor people in<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of a cash transfer. After all, if <strong>the</strong> poorrecipient is most in need of legal services, shecan spend <strong>the</strong> transfer on such services. If sheneeds something else more, <strong>the</strong>n she can allocate<strong>the</strong> transfer to that need instead. The point is notthat general redistribution in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of welfarebenefits should always be preferred to re<strong>for</strong>mstargeted specifically at justice services. Ra<strong>the</strong>r,thinking about <strong>the</strong> comparison to general redistributionis useful because it <strong>for</strong>ces <strong>the</strong> analystto approach <strong>the</strong> problem of access to justice interms of what can be improved in <strong>the</strong> system ofdelivery of such services ra<strong>the</strong>r than in terms of‘unmet need’.Applied to access to justice, <strong>the</strong> challenge canthus be phrased in <strong>the</strong> following terms. Start withinvestigating <strong>the</strong> legal needs of <strong>the</strong> poor, <strong>the</strong>nlook <strong>for</strong> strategies that increase <strong>the</strong> quality ofwhat people get when <strong>the</strong>y try to obtain accessto justice, and decrease <strong>the</strong> costs. Phrased in<strong>the</strong>se terms, <strong>the</strong> size of this challenge becomesapparent. In order to ensure that legal servicesreach <strong>the</strong> poor, quantum jumps in price/quality(Prahalad and Hart 2002) should be achieved.The case study presented in Section 2 regardingaccess to legal identity shows how difficult thiscan be in practice. Even a procedure that aimsto register simple data and provide citizens withmeans to prove <strong>the</strong>ir identity is difficult to organisein a way that effectively reaches out to <strong>the</strong>poor. Fortunately, it also shows where strategiesto improve access may be located.First, users weigh <strong>the</strong> costs of access againstexpected benefits. If costs are higher <strong>the</strong>nbenefits, <strong>the</strong>y are not likely to register. Thesecosts can have many different <strong>for</strong>ms. A mo<strong>the</strong>rwanting to register her five-year-old child mayhave to travel, pay fees, spend time to obtaindocuments, or consult a specialist in legal services.The benefits of accessing <strong>the</strong> procedurecan be huge. A child obtaining a registration isallowed to go to school or can get health care.Similarly, resolving a dispute about water withina community may lead to better use of land thathas to be irrigated and lead to improved, morestable and more productive relationships. However,as <strong>the</strong> example of access to identity registrationshows, <strong>the</strong>re can be hidden disadvantages.Claiming rights may increase one’s visibility asan object of exploitation, or as a citizen that hasto pay tax without corresponding benefits. Thus,access to justice will not materialise unless itsbenefits outweigh its costs.Next, in order to organise access to registrationservices, a quite substantive government infra-16


structure is necessary. This is even more so <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> complex interventions of <strong>the</strong> legal system.Establishing <strong>the</strong> rule of law requires a smooth interactionof many different institutions that cooperateto per<strong>for</strong>m complicated tasks. A functioninglegal system has mechanisms <strong>for</strong> lawmaking inplace, but also <strong>for</strong> facilitating settlement, neutralfact-finding, neutral decisions in disputes, anden<strong>for</strong>cement of rights. Police, courts, prisons,lawyers, and clients <strong>the</strong>mselves <strong>for</strong>m a very complicatedsupply chain. This is also true to someextent <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal systems. What its clients getdepends on local mechanisms that create socialnorms, <strong>the</strong> possibilities to challenge <strong>the</strong>m if necessary,<strong>the</strong> quality of <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>um that deals with<strong>the</strong>ir grievances, and <strong>the</strong> local ways of acceptingand implementing decisions.What helps, is to give people choice. Multiplepoints of access do not only liberate <strong>the</strong> poor in<strong>the</strong> sense that <strong>the</strong>y increase <strong>the</strong> odds that interventionsfit <strong>the</strong>ir problems. They also trigger aninnovation process in which it becomes transparentthat <strong>the</strong> poor prefer some ways of delivering justiceservices above o<strong>the</strong>rs. This gives service providersincentives to improve what <strong>the</strong>y deliver. Choicesare already part of <strong>the</strong> realities of access to justice.People have choices between access to in<strong>for</strong>malprocedures and <strong>for</strong>mal ones. Choices between different<strong>for</strong>ms of alternative dispute resolution (ADR)and choices between settlement and decision bya neutral party. Although having more choice caninitially lead to higher costs in <strong>the</strong> search <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>most appropriate approach, it is a sure way, in <strong>the</strong>long run, to empower <strong>the</strong> poor. Finally, choice is aweapon against <strong>the</strong> new dependencies a legal systemcreates. Instead of depending on <strong>the</strong>ir opponent,disputants become dependent on professionalswith a dedicated and protected position: governmentofficials, licensed lawyers, official judges,or <strong>the</strong> powerful in <strong>the</strong>ir community. Increasedchoice may be <strong>the</strong> answer to <strong>the</strong> monopolies thatcome with official positions.The case of registration also shows in which directionto search <strong>for</strong> approaches to reduce <strong>the</strong>costs of legal services. Interactive computer systemsthat let people per<strong>for</strong>m some registrationtasks <strong>the</strong>mselves, mobile registration units, andbundling registration with o<strong>the</strong>r services are butexamples of a more general class of opportunities.In <strong>the</strong> European Middle Ages, kings andnobles travelling <strong>the</strong> country were offering mobiledispute resolution services. Social w<strong>ork</strong>ers helppeople to sort out <strong>the</strong> problems of life, and maybundle this with valuable pieces of legal advice.Filing grievances online can save travel costs and<strong>the</strong> costs of intake by professionals. If citizensobtain access to <strong>the</strong> right in<strong>for</strong>mation, self-helpcan not only empower <strong>the</strong>m, but also relieve <strong>the</strong>supply chain of costly tasks.A related lesson from <strong>the</strong> registration example isthat it shows how liaisons can be <strong>for</strong>med. A legalsystem functions by <strong>for</strong>ging productive links: between<strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>mal; between governmentservices and services provided by <strong>the</strong> market;between settlement negotiations and <strong>the</strong> shadowof a neutral decision; between clients and professionals.Rule of law is a combination of publicgoods (laws, in<strong>for</strong>mation, neutral interventions bypolice and courts) and services delivered by privatesuppliers (private safety measures, self help,legal services, neutral interventions from ADR,local justice, religious institutions).The last lesson is that politics matters. Exclusionor limiting access can be profitable <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> onesalready inside <strong>the</strong> system, as <strong>the</strong> examples aboutethnic groups that are denied legal identity show.One way or <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r inclusion should be mademore attractive <strong>for</strong> insiders. Naming, shaming,or o<strong>the</strong>r sanctions can achieve this, and probably17


even better, by showing <strong>the</strong> ones with power <strong>the</strong>benefits of increased security, or of a larger classof prosperous customers.This analysis also suggests which <strong>the</strong>oretical conceptsand strands of empirical knowledge can behelpful to improve access to justice:- Political economy and sociology can help toidentify <strong>the</strong> deals that have to be <strong>for</strong>ged inorder to facilitate inclusion.- The image of delivery of justice through asupply chain, points towards <strong>the</strong> perspectivesof transaction costs economics and logistics(supply chain management).- Legal anthropology, law and sociology, negotiation<strong>the</strong>ory, conflict resolution <strong>the</strong>ory andgame <strong>the</strong>ory can yield valuable in<strong>for</strong>mationabout <strong>the</strong> construction of environments tha<strong>the</strong>lp people to settle <strong>the</strong>ir differences.- Removing barriers to justice and <strong>the</strong> similaritiesto <strong>the</strong> delivery of health care or education,suggest remedies that emphasise <strong>the</strong> efficientcorrection of market failures (Shavell 1997,Barendrecht and van Nispen 2007). While <strong>the</strong>‘unmet legal needs’ framew<strong>ork</strong> typically leadsdirectly to proposals to increase legal aid subsidiesor build a better <strong>for</strong>mal legal infrastructure,<strong>the</strong> market failure framew<strong>ork</strong> both offersmore guidance on how to allocate scarcelegal aid subsidies and suggests o<strong>the</strong>r sorts ofstructural re<strong>for</strong>ms that can improve access tojustice.- Knowing that <strong>the</strong> supply of justice is not apure market transaction, but involves publicgoods as well, and requires a substantial neutralinfrastructure invites <strong>the</strong> perspectives ofgovernment failure and of public management.- Many of <strong>the</strong> issues discussed above, and <strong>the</strong>links between access to justice and economicdevelopment, are topics studied by new institutionaleconomics, a body of thought thatemphasises <strong>the</strong> importance of public sectorinstitutions, including <strong>the</strong> legal system, ingenerating economic growth, and also focuseson transaction costs (North 1990).As we proceed with this section, we will discussfour strategies to improve access tojustice that have proven <strong>the</strong>ir value in practice,or seem to be particularly promising, and link<strong>the</strong>m to <strong>the</strong>se <strong>the</strong>oretical concepts. Our focuswill be on <strong>the</strong> need to respond to <strong>the</strong> essentialchallenge: how can <strong>the</strong> justness and fairness ofwhat is delivered be improved, and, in particular,how can costs are decreased? For this reason, <strong>the</strong>reduction of transaction costs figures prominentlyin our analysis.We start at <strong>the</strong> client end of <strong>the</strong> supply chain,with concerns about facilitating self-help, education,and with <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical concept of imperfectin<strong>for</strong>mation. Then we turn to <strong>the</strong> provisionof legal services, using primarily a market failureperspective. Following this we will review strategiesto develop procedures that are better suitedto <strong>the</strong> legal needs and <strong>the</strong> resources of <strong>the</strong> poor.The potential of in<strong>for</strong>mal justice, and its links to<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal legal system, are discussed at <strong>the</strong> endof this section.Enabling Self Help with In<strong>for</strong>mationand Community OrganisingFor a person with limited resources trying to getaccess to justice, <strong>the</strong> first (and sometimes <strong>the</strong>only) option is to decide what she can do herself.Her time may be less scarce than money. If shecan find ways to solve <strong>the</strong> problem without payinglegal fees that is what she will tend to prefer. Soa first strategy <strong>for</strong> legal empowerment may be toenhance <strong>the</strong> possibilities <strong>for</strong> self-help in <strong>the</strong> areaof access to justice.18


The W<strong>ork</strong>ing Group has noted that this is a topicthat has not yet attracted sufficient attention inacademic thinking about access to justice. Thereis a certain tendency to equate access to justicewith access to legal services, assuming that <strong>the</strong>only road to justice leads through lawyers andcourts. This is rapidly changing, however, nowthat even <strong>the</strong> Western world discovers that manypeople appear in courts without legal representationand that in<strong>for</strong>mation about legal rights anddispute resolution is an essential tool <strong>for</strong> empowerment,as well as <strong>for</strong> prevention of social strife.The UK government even set up a Public LegalEducation and Support (PLEAS) Task Force. Atthis stage, however, <strong>the</strong> available in<strong>for</strong>mation islimited, and this is certainly an issue on whichfur<strong>the</strong>r research is warranted.In<strong>for</strong>mation about Norms: Legal EducationWithin this strategy that encourages self-help,know-how about legal norms is essential. Poorpeople may not receive <strong>the</strong> protection or opportunitiesto which <strong>the</strong>y are legally entitled because<strong>the</strong>y do not know <strong>the</strong> law or do not know how togo about securing <strong>the</strong> assistance of someone whocan provide <strong>the</strong> necessary help. This lack of in<strong>for</strong>mationengenders vulnerability to exploitation andabuse, and impedes legal empowerment (NCLEPKenya 2007, NCLEP Philippines 2007). In manydeveloping countries, simply finding out what<strong>the</strong> law is can be a time-consuming and costlyendeavour. In Bangladesh, <strong>for</strong> instance, <strong>the</strong> governmentonly publishes a small number of copiesof <strong>the</strong> statutes passed by Parliament, and <strong>the</strong>sewere available only to those who pay a fee. Thefew public libraries in Bangladesh suffer from anacute shortage of legal resources (Afroz 2006).In Tajikistan, new statutes are typically publishedonly in <strong>the</strong> Parliamentary Gazette, which is notwidely accessible, and ministerial decrees arenot published at all. This makes <strong>the</strong> simple taskof figuring out what <strong>the</strong> law is a time-consumingchore even <strong>for</strong> a trained legal professional (ADB2002). Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, many countries draft andadminister <strong>the</strong> law only in <strong>the</strong> national language(often <strong>the</strong> language of <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mer colonial government),which many of <strong>the</strong> poor do not speak. Thislanguage barrier creates a significant transactioncost <strong>for</strong> poor people who might o<strong>the</strong>rwise avail<strong>the</strong>mselves of <strong>the</strong> legal system. 4An obvious way to remedy this is to in<strong>for</strong>m peoplemore broadly about norms and interventions that<strong>the</strong>y may have to rely on. In<strong>for</strong>mation technologyis arguably <strong>the</strong> most promising avenue <strong>for</strong>this, now that <strong>the</strong> poor will increasingly have accessto internet connections close to <strong>the</strong> placeswhere <strong>the</strong>y live. Preferably, such in<strong>for</strong>mationmust address <strong>the</strong> practical priorities of specificpopulations. Street vendors want to know whichspecific regulations allow <strong>the</strong>m to ply <strong>the</strong>ir trade;what specific lawyers, government offices or nongovernmentalorganisations (NGOs) <strong>the</strong>y can goto <strong>for</strong> help if police harass <strong>the</strong>m; or how to press<strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms of laws that have not yet <strong>for</strong>malised<strong>the</strong>ir status and protected <strong>the</strong>ir livelihoods. Conversely,women living in societies in which <strong>the</strong>laws discriminate against <strong>the</strong>m may be interestedin constitutional provisions or international humanrights treaties that at least provide a basis<strong>for</strong> hope, confidence and activism in favour ofequal rights. The in<strong>for</strong>mation should also begeared towards <strong>the</strong> best practices <strong>for</strong> solving <strong>the</strong>problems <strong>the</strong> poor face. What are <strong>the</strong> rules and<strong>the</strong> best ways <strong>for</strong> solving inheritance problems? Afarmer w<strong>ork</strong>ing <strong>for</strong> years on a plot of land who isconfronted by o<strong>the</strong>rs who show him a deed thatseems to prove <strong>the</strong>ir property-rights will probablywant to know <strong>the</strong> going rate <strong>for</strong> settling such aproblem, instead of getting abstract in<strong>for</strong>mationfrom <strong>the</strong> civil code about property and leasingcontracts (Barendrecht and Van Nispen 2007).19


A related option is teaching <strong>the</strong> poor about<strong>the</strong>ir rights. It can show <strong>the</strong>m that <strong>the</strong> law ison <strong>the</strong>ir side, or that it is deficient and shouldbe changed, or that <strong>the</strong>y should be confidentin pressing <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m of bad laws or <strong>the</strong>implementation of good ones. Non-<strong>for</strong>mal legaleducation (NLE, as opposed to <strong>for</strong>mal law schooleducation) is geared toward making <strong>the</strong> disadvantagedmore legally self-sufficient by building<strong>the</strong>ir legal capacities. It can take place throughcommunity training sessions, radio and televisionbroadcasts, <strong>the</strong>atre plays, and printed and audiovisualmaterials and, as discussed below, paralegaldevelopment. A crucial point about <strong>the</strong>seeducational ef<strong>for</strong>ts is that <strong>the</strong>y must be pitchedat <strong>the</strong> levels of sophistication of lay people and<strong>the</strong>ir particular situation. Effective NLE typicallyborrows from more general international developmentpedagogy in that it is interactive and creative.It may feature such techniques as discussions,games, role-playing and quizzes.Be<strong>for</strong>e interventions are considered, however, itis useful to investigate what causes <strong>the</strong> lack ofin<strong>for</strong>mation, why market <strong>for</strong>ces do not provide asolution <strong>for</strong> this, and what are <strong>the</strong> consequencesof this lack of in<strong>for</strong>mation <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> provision ofjustice services to <strong>the</strong> poor. In an efficient market<strong>for</strong> justice services, prospective consumers wouldbe able to evaluate <strong>the</strong>ir own legal needs andseek out appropriate providers. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, consumerin<strong>for</strong>mation about <strong>the</strong> nature and qualityof <strong>the</strong> legal services offered would ensure that <strong>the</strong>market price <strong>for</strong> legal services reflects <strong>the</strong> valueof that service to consumers. Not all prospectiveconsumers need to be perfectly in<strong>for</strong>med,because <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>the</strong>mselves would conveyin<strong>for</strong>mation (cf. Schwartz and Wilde 1979).None<strong>the</strong>less, a critical mass of in<strong>for</strong>med potentialconsumers is necessary <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> market to allocatelegal services efficiently. If a population of potentialconsumers lacks sufficient basic in<strong>for</strong>mationon what legal services are available, <strong>the</strong>ir benefitsand costs <strong>the</strong>y involve, and how to evaluate <strong>the</strong>irquality, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> market is unlikely to allocatelegal services efficiently even if potential consumerswould be willing to pay a price that potentialsuppliers would accept.Lack of sufficient in<strong>for</strong>mation about legal rightsand entitlements, and about available legal services,is thus problematic <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor <strong>the</strong>mselvesand also causes justice services to be insufficientlyresponsive to <strong>the</strong> needs of <strong>the</strong> poor. Butwhy does this lack of in<strong>for</strong>mation arise? In mostmarkets, consumers learn in<strong>for</strong>mation about serviceavailability and quality from three sources.The first source of in<strong>for</strong>mation is <strong>the</strong> suppliers,who typically have an incentive to disseminatein<strong>for</strong>mation about <strong>the</strong> services <strong>the</strong>y provide. Thesecond source of consumer in<strong>for</strong>mation consistsof o<strong>the</strong>r consumers — ei<strong>the</strong>r directly of indirectlythrough <strong>the</strong> price mechanism. The third sourceof in<strong>for</strong>mation is general media coverage. If<strong>the</strong>se three sources of in<strong>for</strong>mation are sufficientin most consumer markets, why might <strong>the</strong>y notbe sufficient to communicate in<strong>for</strong>mation aboutrights and legal services to poor communities?Understanding <strong>the</strong> answer to this question willhelp re<strong>for</strong>mers design interventions that are appropriatelytargeted to <strong>the</strong> underlying problems.We consider first <strong>the</strong> question. Why might legalservice providers not disseminate <strong>the</strong> relevantin<strong>for</strong>mation? There are several likely explanations.First, <strong>the</strong>re may not be providers willing to offerlegal services to a given population at <strong>the</strong> priceconsumers would be willing or able to pay. If thatis <strong>the</strong> reason, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> lack of legal in<strong>for</strong>mationis a consequence of some o<strong>the</strong>r market failure.This suggests that lack of legal in<strong>for</strong>mation maysometimes be more symptom than disease. Second,general in<strong>for</strong>mation about legal rights and20


entitlements is a public good. If expected profitsfrom providing legal services to a poor communityare relatively low and <strong>the</strong> costs of disseminatingin<strong>for</strong>mation to that community are relatively high,<strong>the</strong>re may be insufficient incentives <strong>for</strong> any onejustice provider to supply in<strong>for</strong>mation. <strong>Law</strong>yers,courts, or ADR providers may have little reasonto in<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong>ir possible clients about <strong>the</strong> rules<strong>the</strong>y need to solve <strong>the</strong>ir problems. This problemis likely especially acute with respect to legalin<strong>for</strong>mation that is not immediately connected to<strong>the</strong> need to hire a legal professional. Third, somecountries impose stringent restrictions on advertising<strong>for</strong> legal services and on <strong>the</strong> unauthorisedpractice of law, and <strong>the</strong>se professional conductrules. Although <strong>the</strong>se restrictions are sometimesdefended as necessary to protect vulnerable consumersfrom deceptive or misleading in<strong>for</strong>mation,<strong>the</strong>y may also make it difficult <strong>for</strong> service providersto disseminate useful in<strong>for</strong>mation (Rhode2000, Barton 2001).These observations suggest that eliminating manyof <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r market failures discussed later in thischapter may also redress <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mational problem,as legal service providers will have an incentiveto communicate more about legal entitlementsand how to defend <strong>the</strong>m. Thus, while it isoften supposed that disseminating more in<strong>for</strong>mationabout legal rights is <strong>the</strong> first step in promotingaccess to justice, it may sometimes turn outthat improvements on this dimension follow o<strong>the</strong>rre<strong>for</strong>ms without <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> substantial additionalgovernment or donor spending. Also, an in<strong>for</strong>mation-disseminationstrategy that relies in largemeasure on private service providers requires aliberal policy toward <strong>the</strong> advertising of legal servicesand <strong>the</strong> solicitation of clients. While manycountries have traditionally viewed legal advertisingand solicitation as unseemly, overly aggressiveprohibitions of <strong>the</strong>se activities may stifle <strong>the</strong>effective communication of legal in<strong>for</strong>mation. Inaddition to relying on individual service providersto disseminate in<strong>for</strong>mation, bar associationsand o<strong>the</strong>r lawyers’ organisations are a naturalcandidate <strong>for</strong> educating <strong>the</strong> public about law andlegal services. Because <strong>the</strong>se organisations represent<strong>the</strong> legal profession as a whole, <strong>the</strong>y canassist lawyers in overcoming <strong>the</strong> collective actionproblem that reduces <strong>the</strong> incentives of individuallegal service providers to disseminate in<strong>for</strong>mationabout legal rights. Bar associations, however,might have too little incentive to disseminatein<strong>for</strong>mation about legal services providers o<strong>the</strong>rthan lawyers, such as paralegals.With respect to <strong>the</strong> second source of in<strong>for</strong>mation,o<strong>the</strong>r consumers, when a serviceis consumed only rarely within a given population,<strong>the</strong>n o<strong>the</strong>r potential consumers are unlikelyto be a useful source of in<strong>for</strong>mation. This suggests<strong>the</strong> possibility of a vicious circle in which adearth of in<strong>for</strong>mation about legal rights and legalservices leads to limited use of <strong>the</strong> legal system,and limited use of <strong>the</strong> legal system perpetuates<strong>the</strong> lack of in<strong>for</strong>mation about law and legal services.This problem is likely to be especially acutewhen social netw<strong>ork</strong>s <strong>for</strong> sharing in<strong>for</strong>mation arerelatively small and insular. To address this problem,re<strong>for</strong>mers should streng<strong>the</strong>n in<strong>for</strong>mationsharingnetw<strong>ork</strong>s that allow transmission of in<strong>for</strong>mationabout law and legal in<strong>for</strong>mation. Buildingnetw<strong>ork</strong>s of legal service providers, NGOs, andcommunity advocacy groups can go a long way toincreasing <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal dissemination of legal in<strong>for</strong>mation.Additionally, <strong>the</strong> dissemination of legalin<strong>for</strong>mation is likely to be more effective when legalservices are integrated with o<strong>the</strong>r social servicesprovided by an umbrella NGO. Unin<strong>for</strong>medpotential consumers are unlikely to seek out alegal service provider if <strong>the</strong>y do not even know<strong>the</strong>y have a legal problem. But if <strong>the</strong>y seek out21


some o<strong>the</strong>r trusted service provider and discuss<strong>the</strong>ir problem, and that service provider has anadequate knowledge of <strong>the</strong> legal system, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>potential legal services consumer is more likelyto learn that her problem has a legal dimensionand that she can seek some <strong>for</strong>m of legal redress.This is yet ano<strong>the</strong>r argument <strong>for</strong> ‘bundling’ legalservices with o<strong>the</strong>r social services (ADB 2001a).Third, even when all <strong>the</strong> above strategies havebeen implemented, <strong>the</strong>re is likely to be a residualneed <strong>for</strong> governments or donor-subsidised disseminationof legal in<strong>for</strong>mation, especially generalizedlegal in<strong>for</strong>mation or in<strong>for</strong>mation that is notimmediately connected to an ongoing or imminentdispute. For this sort of targeted legal in<strong>for</strong>mationdissemination, governments and NGOscan make use of <strong>the</strong> mass media or <strong>the</strong> Internet.Linguistic barriers (including both language barriersand illiteracy), cultural barriers, and a weakcommunications infrastructure (including limitedaccess to radios and televisions) may limit <strong>the</strong>effectiveness of mass media. Different nationalmedia also differ in <strong>the</strong>ir propensity to devote attentionto legal issues. Experience suggests that<strong>the</strong> best approach to mass legal education is touse a mix of print media (both newspapers andpamphlets), posters, radio, and television, alongwith strategies that integrate legal in<strong>for</strong>mationinto popular entertainment such as comic books,soap operas, popular music, local <strong>the</strong>atre, andinteractive, participatory activities (ADB 2001a,Abdur-Rahman et al. 2006).However, it should be emphasised that knowledgeusually is not enough. Farmers may learn that<strong>the</strong>y are entitled to land. But that knowledge isuseless if government personnel, <strong>the</strong> military, acompany or a landlord are powerful enough toignore <strong>the</strong> law, sometimes by corrupting or intimidating<strong>the</strong> police, <strong>the</strong> courts or land ministryofficials. Thus, promoting knowledge of <strong>the</strong> lawis worthwhile, but as a stand-alone strategy itseldom galvanises legal empowerment. And assumingthat knowledge is power can be counterproductiveif it confines legal empowerment strategiesto simply teaching people <strong>the</strong>ir rights.Self Help Interventions: Forming of Peer GroupsIn <strong>the</strong> experience of <strong>the</strong> disadvantaged, it oftenis more correct to say that “organising ispower.” We saw that besides knowledge about <strong>the</strong>norms that fit <strong>the</strong>ir problems, access to justicealso implies that <strong>the</strong>re is a credible threat of anintervention. To assert <strong>the</strong>ir rights, <strong>the</strong> disadvantagedoften have to organise around mutual interests.A woman may know that it is illegal <strong>for</strong> herhusband to beat her. But she may only be able tomake him stop if <strong>the</strong> women in her communityband toge<strong>the</strong>r to shame him, pressure o<strong>the</strong>rwiseindifferent police to take action, persuade malecommunity leaders to intervene or seek <strong>the</strong> helpof lawyers or NGOs. In this way, <strong>the</strong>y can increase<strong>the</strong> incentives on <strong>the</strong>ir partners or <strong>the</strong>ir opponentsto live up to norms.Sometimes community organising (or organisinggroups within a community) can directly targetproblems such as violence against women, lackof land title or property <strong>the</strong>ft. Under o<strong>the</strong>r circumstances,where civil society is too weak orentrenched and opposition too strong, a more indirectapproach may be necessary. Group <strong>for</strong>mationaround relatively ‘safe’ development issues such aslivelihood, micro-credit or reproductive health canpave <strong>the</strong> way <strong>for</strong> more assertive action down <strong>the</strong>line, as <strong>the</strong> groups and <strong>the</strong>ir NGO partners gainmore credibility in <strong>the</strong>ir communities. Later, once<strong>the</strong>ir group has established some credibility, andif <strong>the</strong>y so desire, it is possible to focus on morerights-oriented w<strong>ork</strong>. Women in Bangladesh have<strong>the</strong>reby benefited from integration of legal empowermentinto a reproductive health programme22


From an economic perspective this strategyaims create an efficient, effective system <strong>for</strong>delivering legal services. The following analysiswill again be in<strong>for</strong>med by a transaction costs andmarket failure framew<strong>ork</strong>. This approach is unconventional:most discussion of access to justiceproceeds (1) from <strong>the</strong> observation that poor peoplehave unmet legal needs, to (2) <strong>the</strong> assumptionthat <strong>the</strong> best way to remedy this problem isto provide subsidised legal services, to (3) <strong>the</strong>conclusion that governments and donors shouldincrease funding <strong>for</strong> various <strong>for</strong>ms of legal aid.The usual discussion <strong>the</strong>n focuses on <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mthat legal aid services should take — whe<strong>the</strong>r<strong>the</strong>y should be delivered by governments orNGOs, whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y should emphasise lawyers,law students, or paralegals, how <strong>the</strong>y should befunded, and so <strong>for</strong>th. Our w<strong>ork</strong>ing group suggeststhat this view of improving access to legal servicesis too narrow. When one defines <strong>the</strong> problemnot as ‘unmet legal need’, but ra<strong>the</strong>r as somespecific failure or distortion in <strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong>legal services, a variety of approaches o<strong>the</strong>r thandirect subsidisation emerge, and <strong>the</strong> appropriatescope <strong>for</strong> subsidised legal aid services becomesmore refined and more focused.Lower Cost Delivery Models: ParalegalsParalegals and law students are critically importantto improving legal service delivery to poorcommunities. The term ‘paralegal’ may be somewhatmisleading insofar as it suggests an assistantwho per<strong>for</strong>ms ministerial legal tasks. Paralegalsin many developing country programmes arebetter thought of as community activists who notonly have a basic training not in legal principles,but also a familiarity with local community normsand practices and an ability to offer advice andadvocacy services that go beyond narrow legaladvice. Many paralegal programmes have provenefficient and effective in expanding legal assistancein poor communities (McClymont and Golub2000, McQuoid-Mason 2000, and Maru 2006).A particularly notable example is <strong>the</strong> Timap <strong>for</strong>Justice Initiative in Sierra Leone, which hashelped poor individuals deal with problems likecorruption in government service delivery, domesticviolence and child support, and some criminalmatters (Maru 2006).<strong>Law</strong> students are ano<strong>the</strong>r relatively cost-effectiveway to invest scarce legal aid resources. Legalaid clinics staffed by law students or recent lawschool graduates in Russia, Ukraine, South Africa,India, and elsewhere have demonstratedremarkable competence in delivering valuablelegal aid services to poor communities at low cost(Golub 2004, USAID 2002). There<strong>for</strong>e, governmentsand donors who have to allocate a limitedlegal aid budget might do well to place more emphasison supporting <strong>the</strong> activities of paralegalsand law student clinics.Streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong> national bar association anddeveloping an effective w<strong>ork</strong>ing relationship with<strong>the</strong> bar is important in developing effective targetedlegal aid programmes, especially when <strong>the</strong>services of attorneys are required. Although oneto-onelawyer-client relationships would normallynot be af<strong>for</strong>dable by <strong>the</strong> poor, nor perhaps bygovernments or donors who might subsidise legalaid, <strong>the</strong>re could be a role here to be played bybar associations. They could help to ga<strong>the</strong>r anddisseminate in<strong>for</strong>mation in <strong>the</strong> legal communityabout access to justice issues, and provide useful<strong>for</strong>mal or in<strong>for</strong>mal oversights. They could, moreover,offer political support <strong>for</strong> access to justicere<strong>for</strong>m and increased funding <strong>for</strong> necessary legalaid services, help to determine <strong>the</strong> most worthycandidates <strong>for</strong> targeted legal aid subsidies, andpossibly sponsor continuing legal education programmesconcerned with meeting <strong>the</strong> legal needsof <strong>the</strong> poor. It is, of course, possible that some24


ar associations might be wary of certain approachesto legal services re<strong>for</strong>m (such as thosethat call <strong>for</strong> increasing competition in <strong>the</strong> provisionof legal services or reducing <strong>the</strong> demand<strong>for</strong> legal services); or, <strong>the</strong>y might be excessivelyenthusiastic about o<strong>the</strong>r approaches (those, <strong>for</strong>example, that call <strong>for</strong> large government or donorsubsidies to lawyers who offer legal aid services).Access to justice re<strong>for</strong>mers cannot ignore <strong>the</strong> bar,even where those structures are weak and disorganised,because <strong>the</strong> long-term sustainability ofsubsidised legal aid programmes will also haveto depend on <strong>the</strong> support and collaboration of astrong and motivated lawyers’ association.Legal Services that Empower <strong>the</strong> ClientsQuality of legal services matters as much as cost,however. In fact, <strong>the</strong> conventional approach tolegal services envisions experts providing technicalassistance to needy clients. This approach isnot concerned with clients’ agency or empowermentoutside <strong>the</strong> pursuit of redress <strong>for</strong> any givenlegal claim. Some legal services ef<strong>for</strong>ts do consciouslyseek to empower <strong>the</strong> people with whom<strong>the</strong>y w<strong>ork</strong>. Empowerment techniques includeincorporating education into every aspect ofservice delivery, w<strong>ork</strong>ing with and streng<strong>the</strong>ningcommunity organisations, organising collectiveaction to address justice problems, and engagingin community education and community dialogueon justice issues. Paralegal approaches may beattractive, <strong>the</strong>n, not simply <strong>for</strong> cost advantagesbut also because paralegals may be better positionedto engage in a broader, empowermentorientedmethod of legal service delivery. In <strong>the</strong>end, however, this is a matter of philosophy andattitude, ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> professional status of <strong>the</strong>legal service provider.This creates a need <strong>for</strong> appropriate training.W<strong>ork</strong>ing with <strong>the</strong> poor involves a set of skills thatis quite different from what most law schoolsteach and what most lawyers practice. Mechanisms<strong>for</strong> inculcating <strong>the</strong>se development-orientedskills and perspectives are NGO internships <strong>for</strong>law students and young lawyers and law schoolclinical legal education programmes. The resultis ‘development lawyering’, as it is sometimescalled, which can involve a willingness to trek outto <strong>the</strong> remote rural areas or into crowded slums.It can equally involve viewing litigation as a lastresort and administrative advocacy, alternativedispute resolution and building of <strong>the</strong> poor legalcapacities as preferred options. Such lawyeringfrequently requires skills suitable <strong>for</strong> carryingout non<strong>for</strong>mal legal education — interactivetechniques ra<strong>the</strong>r than lectures. It involves anawareness of how <strong>the</strong> law can relate to o<strong>the</strong>r developmentfields. This includes viewing <strong>the</strong> disadvantagedas partners with whom to strategiseon law re<strong>for</strong>m and implementation. Similarly, itincludes listening ra<strong>the</strong>r than dictating to clients— <strong>the</strong> hallmark of any good lawyer, but particularlychallenging in helping impoverished peoplewho usually defer to more educated and affluentindividuals.This type of service may be desirable, but it is notyet clear whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y <strong>for</strong>m a sustainable businessmodel and this may be one of <strong>the</strong> reasonsthat <strong>the</strong>re is little spontaneous supply of <strong>the</strong>seempowering legal services. Suppliers may be hesitantto empower <strong>the</strong>ir clients to solve problemsby <strong>the</strong>mselves, because <strong>the</strong>y may fear this leadsto loss of future business.Alternative Dispute ResolutionAno<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>m of broadening legal services is toexpand <strong>the</strong> use of various <strong>for</strong>ms of alternativedispute resolution (ADR), including small claimscourts, as well as arbitration, mediation, and conciliation(Lopez-de-Silanes 2002, Hammergren25


2007). Such mechanisms prove preferable <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor because <strong>the</strong>y are more accessible thancourts, af<strong>for</strong>dable, comprehensible and (often)effective. They can include government administrativetribunals, where paralegals can sometimesprovide representation, such as <strong>for</strong> agrarianre<strong>for</strong>m and labour disputes in <strong>the</strong> Philippines.Third party arbitration courts have been set up inmany countries of <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mer Soviet Union where,in connection with livelihood projects, <strong>the</strong> partiesselect arbitrators <strong>for</strong> land, agrarian or propertydisputes.This is not to say that ADR is always preferableto, or mutually exclusive with, litigation. It canbe severely hampered by gender biases or o<strong>the</strong>rpower imbalances between disputants (as can<strong>the</strong> courts, however). It is often inappropriate <strong>for</strong>handling criminal conduct, particularly violentconduct (though non-state systems are oftenstill used <strong>for</strong> that purpose). And <strong>the</strong>re are manycontexts, such as with public interest litigation inSouth Africa, where going to court is an effectivelegal implementation strategy.From an economic perspective, ADR is most appropriatewhen <strong>the</strong> primary objective is to resolveindividual disputes over private rights and benefits(Landes and Posner 1979). For those sortsof disputes, <strong>the</strong> case <strong>for</strong> substantial public subsidisationof judicial dispute resolution is muchless compelling — though <strong>the</strong> state may stillneed to supply courts as a backstop to make sure<strong>the</strong> ADR processes comport with basic principlesof fairness. Re<strong>for</strong>mers should attempt, when possible,to steer private disputes into appropriate<strong>for</strong>ms of ADR, and to husband scarce judicialresources <strong>for</strong> disputes that involve public goods(including <strong>the</strong> articulation of norms and principles)and fundamental public values.In addition to <strong>the</strong> arbitration, mediation, and conciliationprogrammes traditionally associated withADR, re<strong>for</strong>mers might also address <strong>the</strong> demand<strong>for</strong> judicial services by encouraging or requiring<strong>the</strong> resolution of more disputes (at least in <strong>the</strong>first instance) in <strong>the</strong> administrative bureaucracyra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> courts. For example, <strong>the</strong> claimsof injured w<strong>ork</strong>ers could be resolved by w<strong>ork</strong>ers’compensation boards ra<strong>the</strong>r than in lawsuitsagainst employers. Consumer issues could bebrought be<strong>for</strong>e easy accessible, low-cost consumercommittees. A similar strategy <strong>for</strong> reducingdemand <strong>for</strong> expensive judicial services is to adoptre<strong>for</strong>ms that allow <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> resolution of certaintypes of disputes according to customary law oro<strong>the</strong>r traditional practices of <strong>the</strong> non-state sector.These approaches raise a host of additionalconcerns related to <strong>the</strong> equity and efficiency of<strong>the</strong> bureaucratic justice system and <strong>the</strong> non-statejustice system, which subsequent sections of thischapter will discuss in more detail. For purposesof <strong>the</strong> present discussion, bureaucratic and customarydispute resolution can be considered asspecial types of ADR.The design of just and effective ADR systemsis itself an enormous topic. It is also a subjectwhere it is difficult to make general recommendations,because <strong>the</strong> optimal design of ADR systemsdepends very much on <strong>the</strong> unique circumstancesof each country. Three concerns aboutADR programmes are especially prominent. Thefirst is that <strong>the</strong>se programmes are often biasedin favour of powerful interests and lack adequatesafeguards to protect less sophisticated parties(UNDP 2005).The second concern is that ADR programmestend to become increasingly ‘proceduralised’over time — that is, <strong>the</strong>y begin to look more likequasi-courts, and <strong>the</strong>y lose <strong>the</strong> cost and speedadvantages that justified <strong>the</strong>ir creation in <strong>the</strong> firstplace. The third concern has to do with <strong>the</strong> final-26


ity of ADR decisions. If it is too easy to challengean ADR ruling in court, <strong>the</strong>n parties do not have asufficient incentive to take ADR seriously (Shavell1995). On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong> harder it is to contestADR decisions, <strong>the</strong> greater <strong>the</strong> concern thatimportant individual rights and entitlements arebeing decided outside of <strong>the</strong> judicial system bynon-state actors.While all of <strong>the</strong>se problems are serious and legitimateconcerns, a number of countries have hadconsiderable success crafting ADR programmesthat reduce <strong>the</strong> burden on <strong>the</strong> judicial systemand increase access at a relatively low cost. InBangladesh, <strong>for</strong> example, local mediation councilsresolve 60 -70 percent of local disputes (US-AID 2002). In Argentina, <strong>the</strong> Ministry of Justiceand USAID supported <strong>the</strong> creation of legal servicecentres in Buenos Aires to provide mediationservices, and <strong>the</strong>se centres appear to have beeneffective (USAID 2002). Again, while <strong>the</strong> designof appropriate ADR programmes is challengingand context-dependent, most available evidenceindicates that developing cost-effective ADR programmesis an important though imperfect meansof providing an alternative to using an overcrowdedcourt system.Bundling with O<strong>the</strong>r ServicesLegal aid programmes are most effective when<strong>the</strong>y are bundled with o<strong>the</strong>r social services ra<strong>the</strong>rthan offered as stand-alone programmes. Forexample, <strong>the</strong> South African Legal Aid Board,which experimented with a variety of models <strong>for</strong>providing civil legal aid, found that <strong>the</strong> most effectivemodel is a ‘justice centre’ model — a ‘onestop legal shop’ that provides comprehensivelegal services through a combination of lawyers,advocates, paralegals, and administrative staff(MacQuoid-Mason 2000). Similarly, many LatinAmerican countries have had success with ‘Casasde Justicia’ (Houses of Justice) that provide assistancewith both legal and non-legal aspectsof common problems, such as child support andcustody issues, property disputes, domestic violence,and administrative matters (USAID 2002).This model may be more effective than state subsidisationof private lawyers and advocates whoprovide legal services to <strong>the</strong> poor.Arelated point is that international donorshave had more success funding local NGOsthat provide a variety of services, including legalservices, than in funding NGOs that provideexclusively legal services. More encompassingorganisations tend to be more effective in reaching<strong>the</strong> target population, and <strong>the</strong>y also tend to bemore sustainable in <strong>the</strong> long term (ADB 2001a).Thus, adding legal services capacity to existingcommunity-based organisations is a more promisingstrategy than supporting or establishing neworganisations that focus exclusively on providinglegal aid. One possible ‘bundling’ strategy thatholds particular promise is <strong>the</strong> integration of legalaid services with microfinance institutions (MFIs).MFIs have regular access to poor communities anda group-based service delivery model well-suited tolegal aid services, especially when collective actionis necessary. Re<strong>for</strong>mers have already begun to experimentwith incorporating health and educationservices within existing MFIs, and early indicationssuggest this integration has been effective (Dun<strong>for</strong>d2002). Adding legal aid services seems like areasonable next stepMany of <strong>the</strong> generic and actual examples citedin this paper reflect how legal implementationcan build on or integrate with o<strong>the</strong>r developmentactivities and fields. In fact, legal empowermentoften is most effective when this takes place.The integration with community organising andgroup <strong>for</strong>mation represents this phenomenon.Ano<strong>the</strong>r example is <strong>the</strong> use of <strong>the</strong> media, which27


can play an important role in mobilising <strong>the</strong> poorto assert <strong>the</strong>ir rights or <strong>the</strong> public to support <strong>the</strong>iradvocacy. In a more substantive vein, <strong>the</strong> urbanpoor and tenant farmers who receive land titlesmay need multi-faceted assistance to make bestuse of <strong>the</strong>ir new property. This can include adviceon and availability of credit programmes <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mer and agricultural technologies <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> latter.Removing Constrictions of <strong>the</strong> Supply of LegalServices to <strong>the</strong> PoorAno<strong>the</strong>r reason why poor individuals may not haveadequate access to legal services is <strong>the</strong> artificialconstriction of <strong>the</strong> supply of legal service providers.In an efficient market, if potential consumersare willing to pay more than it would cost a potentialsupplier to provide a service, <strong>the</strong> providershould enter <strong>the</strong> market to provide <strong>the</strong> service.Collectively, this dynamic should drive <strong>the</strong> priceof <strong>the</strong> service down to an efficient level. However,if barriers to entry prevent potential suppliersfrom entering <strong>the</strong> market, <strong>the</strong> market price willbe artificially high and certain consumers willnot be able to acquire services <strong>the</strong>y would liketo purchase. The excluded consumers are often<strong>the</strong> poor, since <strong>the</strong>y are less able to pay a highermarket price.Many observers believe that this sort of marketfailure is common — perhaps pervasive — in <strong>the</strong>market <strong>for</strong> legal services. There are two primaryreasons why <strong>the</strong> supply of legal service providersmight be artificially constricted. The first has todo with <strong>the</strong> nature of legal education, and <strong>the</strong>second has to do with <strong>the</strong> regulation of <strong>the</strong> legalprofession.With respect to education, <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal legal systemin many countries is <strong>the</strong> province of <strong>the</strong> elite,and this legal elitism extends to <strong>the</strong> way in whichlawyers are trained. Many law schools prepare<strong>the</strong>ir students to practice <strong>the</strong> sort of law that ismost relevant to <strong>the</strong> affluent or to <strong>the</strong> internationalbusiness community, and <strong>the</strong> population of lawstudents is often drawn disproportionately from<strong>the</strong> more well-to-do segment of society. On top ofthis, in many countries <strong>the</strong> number of slots at lawschools is very limited: often <strong>the</strong>re are only oneor two major public law schools with a limitednumber of spaces, and it is difficult <strong>for</strong> privatelaw schools to enter <strong>the</strong> market.The end result is a supply problem: Developingcountry law schools train few lawyersoverall; <strong>the</strong> lawyers that are trained are disproportionatelyinterested in <strong>the</strong> legal problems of<strong>the</strong> elite; and those lawyers who might considerfocusing on <strong>the</strong> legal problems of <strong>the</strong> poor facesubstantial entry barriers because <strong>the</strong>y have notreceived much early training in <strong>the</strong> relevant fieldsand skills (NCLEP Ethiopia 2007). Even if representationof poor clients could prove financiallyor personally rewarding <strong>for</strong> larger numbers of potentiallawyers, distortions in <strong>the</strong> legal educationsystem may entrench distortions in <strong>the</strong> supply ofsuch lawyers relative to what one would observein a hypo<strong>the</strong>tical efficient market.One step that might redress this problem is tomake it easier to enter <strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong> providinglegal education, <strong>for</strong> example by relaxing accreditationrequirements or encouraging distancelearning. Elite lawyers might sneer at ‘nightschool’ or ‘trade school’ lawyers, but expanding<strong>the</strong> opportunities <strong>for</strong> legal education willhelp increase <strong>the</strong> supply of lawyers, especiallylawyers who come from non-elite backgrounds.Additionally, it may be advisable to create andfund more training programmes <strong>for</strong> paralegalsor o<strong>the</strong>r non-lawyer service providers (McLymontand Golub 2000), as well as training programmes<strong>for</strong> practicing lawyers who want to move intopractice areas that emphasise <strong>the</strong> provision oflegal services to poor or o<strong>the</strong>rwise disadvantaged28


clients. The organised bar or o<strong>the</strong>r associations oflegal professionals may be especially helpful inpursuing <strong>the</strong>se goals, especially in <strong>the</strong> contest ofcontinuing legal education.Of course, one must guard against <strong>the</strong> dangersof ‘diploma mills’ that give students alaw degree but not any real skills or training, especiallywhen <strong>the</strong>se fly-by-night operations exploitless educated prospective students. This dangershould not be exaggerated, especially when comparedwith <strong>the</strong> significant costs associated withoverly limited opportunities <strong>for</strong> legal education.Never<strong>the</strong>less, in some developing countries, <strong>the</strong>poor may suffer as much from an ‘oversupply’of poorly-trained, dishonest ‘lawyers’ as <strong>the</strong>y dofrom an under-supply of competent lawyers interestedin representing poor clients. The solutionto <strong>the</strong> quality control problem, however, cannotbe sharp restrictions on access to legal education.Ra<strong>the</strong>r, it must be a combination of sensibleregulation, market competition, and in<strong>for</strong>mationdissemination.In addition to expanding opportunities <strong>for</strong> legaleducation and training, re<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>the</strong> nature oflegal education at <strong>the</strong> elite law schools couldmake it easier <strong>for</strong> young lawyers to pursue careersthat include a substantial amount of public servicew<strong>ork</strong> or compensated representation of poorclients. There is no one right way to do this, anddifferent law schools will necessarily take differentapproaches to curricular re<strong>for</strong>m. With that caveat,possible re<strong>for</strong>ms might include expanding courseofferings on subjects of particular relevance topoor clients (such as landlord-tenant law, labourlaw, land law, natural resources law, customarylaw, mass torts, and criminal defence); providingmore opportunities <strong>for</strong> clinical legal education;and using incentives or requirements to encouragelaw students to spend a period of time aftergraduation doing public interest w<strong>ork</strong> or providinglegal aid. Additionally, elite law schools shouldexplore ways to increase enrolment of studentsfrom disadvantaged backgrounds, and to providespecial classes to such students so that <strong>the</strong>y cancompete with <strong>the</strong>ir classmates from elite backgrounds(Menon 2007). While <strong>the</strong>re is no guaranteethat students from disadvantaged backgroundswill end up providing legal services to <strong>the</strong> poor,<strong>the</strong>y are probably more likely to do so as a statisticalmatter, and <strong>the</strong>y may also serve as role models<strong>for</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r members of <strong>the</strong>ir communities.The risk of an approach that emphasises drawingmore talented young people — especiallytalented young people from disadvantaged backgrounds— into <strong>the</strong> legal profession is that <strong>the</strong>irtalents might be better deployed in some o<strong>the</strong>rfield (Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny 1991). Manywho think and write about legal education andlegal aid have an un<strong>for</strong>tunate tendency to neglect<strong>the</strong> opportunity costs associated with a greaterallocation of talent to <strong>the</strong> legal sector. Never<strong>the</strong>less,in most developing countries <strong>the</strong> supply oflegal service providers in poor communities is soconstricted, and existing law school training isso distorted in <strong>the</strong> direction of preparing younglawyers <strong>for</strong> elite practice, that <strong>the</strong> benefits of expanding<strong>the</strong> opportunities <strong>for</strong> legal education arelikely to exceed whatever costs arise from divertingsome number of talented youths from alternativecareers in business, medicine, science,public service, or some o<strong>the</strong>r calling.Distortion in <strong>the</strong> legal education system is onesource of <strong>the</strong> supply problem in <strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong> legalservices. Ano<strong>the</strong>r potential problem may arisewhen countries adopt stringent ‘unauthorisedpractice of law’ rules — that is, when countriesmandate that certain legal services can only beoffered by a certain legal professionals, such aslicensed attorneys, barristers, or notaries. While<strong>the</strong>se restrictions may arise from <strong>the</strong> purest of29


motives — such as <strong>the</strong> desire to maintain minimumquality standards and to protect consumersfrom exploitation — <strong>the</strong>y often have <strong>the</strong> effectof conferring a monopoly on a particular set oflegal service providers. This drives up <strong>the</strong> priceof legal services to <strong>the</strong> disadvantage of consumersin general and poor consumers in particular(Rhode 2009, 2004, Spaulding 2004). Thisphenomenon has led to calls in some quarters <strong>for</strong>complete elimination of prohibitions on <strong>the</strong> unauthorisedpractice of law, and in o<strong>the</strong>r quarters <strong>for</strong>more modest changes that would allow paralegalsand lay people to per<strong>for</strong>m a larger proportion of<strong>the</strong> activities that are currently restricted to legalprofessionals (Cantrell 2004, Kritzer 1997,Rhode 2004, NCLEP Philippines 2007).Though some bar associations have shown an appreciationof <strong>the</strong> problem and indicated a desireto w<strong>ork</strong> with re<strong>for</strong>mers to liberalise <strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong>legal services, o<strong>the</strong>r legal professional associationshave fiercely opposed any re<strong>for</strong>ms that mightthreaten <strong>the</strong>ir monopoly on legal services (Hammergren2007, Messick 1999). The argumentsagainst loosening restrictions on who can providelegal services typically emphasise <strong>the</strong> need to protectconsumers from incompetent or unscrupulousservice providers. Of course, many service marketsfunction effectively without strict ex ante licensingschemes and entry barriers, so <strong>the</strong> case <strong>for</strong> thissort of regulation in <strong>the</strong> legal services context ishardly self-evident. Moreover, <strong>the</strong>re is a small butgrowing body of empirical research — most of it,admittedly, conducted in rich countries — thatindicates non-lawyers (especially paralegals) andlay people can per<strong>for</strong>m a variety of ‘legal’ servicesas effectively as lawyers, and that marketmechanisms and less intrusive regulation can beeffective in protecting consumers from exploitation(Cantrell 2004, Kritzer 1997, Domberger andSherr 1989). This evidence, though suggestivera<strong>the</strong>r than conclusive, indicates that liberalisationof <strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong> legal services — in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m ofweakening restrictions on who can provide particularlegal services — is likely to improve access tojustice <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor substantially, while imposingrelatively few costs on society so long as alternativequality-control institutions are in place.A major attraction of a re<strong>for</strong>m strategy that emphasises<strong>the</strong> liberalisation of <strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong> legal servicesis that, compared to many o<strong>the</strong>r legal re<strong>for</strong>mstrategies, liberalisation may require fewer governmentor donor expenditures, at least in <strong>the</strong> medium-to long-term. Instead of compensating <strong>for</strong> amarket distortion through continuous payments to<strong>the</strong> individuals, <strong>the</strong> liberalisation strategy focuseson curing a market distortion through a change in<strong>the</strong> regulatory scheme. The major obstacle to <strong>the</strong>liberalisation strategy, however, is likely to be political:As noted above, many (though not all) associationsof legal professionals strongly oppose thissort of liberalisation. Organised legal professionalsare indispensable partners in achieving <strong>the</strong> objectivesof expanding access to justice and promotinglegal empowerment (Grajzl and Murrell 2006), andit would be a serious mistake to alienate <strong>the</strong> barby adopting an overly confrontational posture withrespect to <strong>the</strong> liberalisation in <strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong> legalservices. Though <strong>the</strong> appropriate implementationstrategy will depend on <strong>the</strong> specific circumstancesof each individual case, as a rule of thumb it isprobably advisable <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>mers to w<strong>ork</strong> with <strong>the</strong>bar to find points of agreement and opportunities<strong>for</strong> collaboration; to begin <strong>the</strong> process of liberalising<strong>the</strong> legal services market with those legalservices where <strong>the</strong> most powerful lawyers andlawyers’ associations are least threatened; and toemphasise <strong>for</strong>ms of liberalisation that increase <strong>the</strong>participation of non-lawyers in contexts were fewlawyers currently offer services.For example, re<strong>for</strong>mers could support special ex-30


ceptions to ‘unauthorised practice’ restrictions <strong>for</strong>paralegals that want to offer legal services in poorrural communities that are not currently servedby many lawyers. Or, re<strong>for</strong>mers could encouragearrangements where non-lawyers provide servicesunder <strong>the</strong> nominal supervision of a licensed legalprofessional (cf. Maru 2006). These gradual firststeps may build political support <strong>for</strong> broader liberalisationof <strong>the</strong> legal services market while at<strong>the</strong> same time reassuring <strong>the</strong> legal establishmentthat doing so will not threaten <strong>the</strong>ir livelihoodor undermine <strong>the</strong> reputation and integrity of <strong>the</strong>profession. A fur<strong>the</strong>r advantage to this gradualistapproach is that it allows <strong>for</strong> regular feedbackand adjustments to make sure that consumer interestsare adequately protected in <strong>the</strong> liberalisedmarket. A badly designed and overly aggressiveliberalisation strategy is likely to backfire if largenumbers of consumers find <strong>the</strong>mselves victimisedby dishonest or incompetent service providers.The fundamental point here is that <strong>the</strong> legal servicesmarket will not operate efficiently <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> benefitof <strong>the</strong> poor if <strong>the</strong> supply of individuals who cansupply legal services to poor people is artificiallyconstricted by <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong> legal educationsystem or by a regulatory regime that restrictsentry excessively. There<strong>for</strong>e, re<strong>for</strong>mers shouldadopt measures, appropriate to <strong>the</strong> particular circumstances,to eliminate both distortions in <strong>the</strong>system of legal education and restrictions on <strong>the</strong>market <strong>for</strong> legal services, when <strong>the</strong>se distortionsand restrictions artificially restrict <strong>the</strong> supply oflegal service providers <strong>for</strong> poor communities.Financing of Claims: Legal Insurance andTargeted Legal AidThe costs of justice services are likely to remainconsiderable, even if <strong>the</strong> broadening suggested in<strong>the</strong> preceding paragraphs would take place. Butindividuals do not need expensive legal servicesfrequently. These events are likely to occur onceor a few times in <strong>the</strong>ir lifetime. Even <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>costs can be limited, unless it is necessary totake <strong>the</strong> issue up to a court <strong>for</strong> litigation and en<strong>for</strong>cement.So it is interesting to consider whe<strong>the</strong>r<strong>the</strong> costs of litigation can be insured by privateor public arrangements, or whe<strong>the</strong>r governmentsshould invest in subsidising <strong>the</strong>se services.• Insofar as legal services confer private benefitson individuals, one might expect that<strong>the</strong>se services would be efficiently suppliedin well-structured private markets. If peoplewould benefit from hiring a lawyer to helpwith a problem or dispute, <strong>the</strong>y will hire one.If <strong>the</strong> cost of securing legal representationexceeds <strong>the</strong> expected value of <strong>the</strong> services,<strong>the</strong>n it would be inefficient to hire a lawyer.But in <strong>the</strong> real world, serious market failurescomplicate this facile characterisation of <strong>the</strong>legal services market. One set of problems,discussed below, is that <strong>the</strong> costs of pursuinga legal claim may deter even those with positiveexpected value claims from retaining <strong>the</strong>necessary legal services. Even if we put thatproblem aside, we would still have to considertwo o<strong>the</strong>r market failures that can leave litigantswho ought to retain a lawyer unable todo so: First, private mechanisms <strong>for</strong> providingoptimal insurance against legal risks are oftenunavailable or inadequate.• Second, many poor people lack access to awell-functioning private market <strong>for</strong> financing<strong>the</strong> pursuit of <strong>the</strong>ir legal claims. Both of <strong>the</strong>seproblems share a common root: poor peoplehave limited assets, but litigation typicallyrequires a relatively large up-front transfer ofresources to a legal services provider.The inadequate insurance problem arises primarilyin cases where a poor individual is <strong>the</strong> target31


of some legal action brought by <strong>the</strong> governmentor ano<strong>the</strong>r party. For example, a poor personmay suddenly find herself <strong>the</strong> target of an evictionproceeding, a private lawsuit, or — mostterrifying of all — a criminal prosecution. Whenthis sort of disaster occurs, <strong>the</strong> individual maysuddenly find herself in need of expensive legalservices, but she may not have sufficient assetson hand to pay <strong>the</strong>se costs herself. One mightreasonably suppose that <strong>the</strong> private value to <strong>the</strong>potential target of having access to such servicesin case of a legal emergency exceeds <strong>the</strong> probability-discountedcost to potential providers ofpromising to make such services available. Ino<strong>the</strong>r contexts where this is <strong>the</strong> case, privatefirst-party insurance markets emerge: The potentiallyneedy individual pays some regular fee to<strong>the</strong> insurer, and in <strong>the</strong> event of emergency <strong>the</strong>insurer pays <strong>the</strong> majority of <strong>the</strong> cost of providing<strong>the</strong> emergency service. But although efficientprivate insurance markets <strong>for</strong> legal services havedeveloped in some parts of Europe (Killian 2003,Regan 2003), <strong>the</strong>y are generally rare elsewhere in<strong>the</strong> world. The lack of effective insurance againstlegal risk burdens <strong>the</strong> poor much more than <strong>the</strong>affluent, because <strong>the</strong> affluent are better able toself-insure — <strong>for</strong> example, by having large ‘rainyday funds’ available to cover un<strong>for</strong>eseen emergencyexpenditures.One reason <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> dearth of effective private legalinsurance arrangements may be <strong>the</strong> genericproblem that very poor individuals devote all <strong>the</strong>irassets to short-term subsistence; <strong>the</strong>y would notbe willing or able to buy legal insurance even if itwere available. Insofar as that is <strong>the</strong> main cause,<strong>the</strong> most obvious solution is straight<strong>for</strong>wardredistribution of wealth ra<strong>the</strong>r than any re<strong>for</strong>mtargeted at legal services specifically. Ano<strong>the</strong>rreason may be that poor people lack sufficientaccess to in<strong>for</strong>mation about <strong>the</strong> benefits of legalinsurance. This consideration is a variant on <strong>the</strong>general concern about <strong>the</strong> lack of adequate legalin<strong>for</strong>mation, considered in a later section.O<strong>the</strong>r reasons <strong>for</strong> a failure in <strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong> legalinsurance involve problems with insurance marketsgenerally. The first problem is ‘moral hazard’:those with insurance are less likely to take care toavoid taking actions that are likely to trigger <strong>the</strong>need <strong>for</strong> insurance coverage. The second problemis ‘adverse selection’: those at greater risk aremore likely to purchase insurance, which leadsto a vicious cycle in which price increases deterpurchases by relatively lower-risk individuals, and<strong>the</strong> increasing concentration of high-risk individualsin <strong>the</strong> insurance pool drives <strong>the</strong> price upfur<strong>the</strong>r (Bolton and Dewatripont 2005). In o<strong>the</strong>rprivate insurance markets, providers and regulatorstry to deal with <strong>the</strong> moral hazard and adverseselection problems through devices like deductiblesand co-payments, price discrimination on<strong>the</strong> basis of risk factors, and mandatory groupinsurance plans. These mechanisms may not beadequate to address <strong>the</strong> problem in <strong>the</strong> context oflegal insurance, however. The result, <strong>the</strong>n, is thatmany people of modest means may not be ableto purchase private insurance against legal risks,even if <strong>the</strong>y are willing and able to do so.One straight<strong>for</strong>ward solution to pervasive failuresin <strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong> legal insurance is <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> stateor <strong>the</strong> international donor community to step in toprovide universal insurance against certain typesof legal risks. The most obvious and widespread<strong>for</strong>m of government-administered legal insuranceis <strong>the</strong> provision of public defenders <strong>for</strong> indigentcriminal defendants. Governments and NGOs thatoffer free or subsidised legal assistance to individualsfighting eviction, defending against civillawsuits, or contesting fines levied by governmentagencies are also essentially providing subsidisedlegal insurance.32


The case <strong>for</strong> government or donor-funded legalinsurance is powerful in <strong>the</strong> presence of <strong>the</strong> marketfailures described above, but it is important torecognise that such insurance is very expensive.It also involves significant redistribution of socialresources — not only from <strong>the</strong> well-off to <strong>the</strong>poor, but among different sub-groups of <strong>the</strong> poor.Subsidised legal insurance does nothing to mitigate<strong>the</strong> moral hazard problem, and it may erodeindividual’s incentives to take precautions to avoidbeing subject to legal action. Subsidised insurancealso reduces <strong>the</strong> incentives of marginally indigentindividuals to self-insure even when <strong>the</strong>y coulddo so (cf. Hoffman, Rubin and Shepherd 2005).Moreover, although <strong>the</strong>re is no adverse selectionproblem under a universal insurance scheme— because opting out is impossible — <strong>the</strong> schemetransfers resources from people who rarely makeuse of emergency legal services to those who use<strong>the</strong>se services more frequently. Often this resourcetransfer takes <strong>the</strong> near-invisible <strong>for</strong>m of <strong>the</strong> opportunitycosts of <strong>the</strong> resources spent on emergencylegal services <strong>for</strong> high-risk individuals and groups.Those resources might o<strong>the</strong>rwise have been spenton o<strong>the</strong>r legal or non-legal services that would benefitdifferent populations of poor individuals.This is not to say that state or donor provisionof emergency legal insurance is a bad idea.Indeed, in some cases — such as <strong>the</strong> provisionof competent criminal defence counsel free ofcharge to indigent defendants — state-fundedlegal insurance may be a moral and legal obligation.But because <strong>the</strong> operation of a universallegal insurance scheme is so costly, it is worthconsidering o<strong>the</strong>r techniques that re<strong>for</strong>mersmight employ to redress <strong>the</strong> failures in <strong>the</strong> market<strong>for</strong> emergency legal insurance. One such approachis to expand <strong>the</strong> use of local communitybasedorganisations that allow individuals to pool<strong>the</strong>ir risk. For example, labour unions can — andoften do — provide legal services on behalf of<strong>the</strong>ir members, especially to contest terminationdecisions and adverse employment conditions.Tenants’ associations can provide emergencylegal assistance to contest evictions; similarly,while landlords’ associations can offer emergencylegal assistance to take action against unruly ordestructive tenants. The advantage of relying onsmall community-based representative groups toprovide emergency legal insurance is that <strong>the</strong>segroups may be better able to monitor and police<strong>the</strong>ir members and to apportion insurance costsin rough proportion to risk.The financing problem typically involves poorindividuals who have some legal claim — ei<strong>the</strong>ra positive legal entitlement or an injury to a legallyprotected interest — that has a positivemonetisable value that is greater than <strong>the</strong> cost of<strong>the</strong> legal services necessary to pursue <strong>the</strong> claim.In an efficient market, because this claim has apositive net expected value, <strong>the</strong> individual shouldbe able to retain representation and receive anaward (perhaps through litigation, but more likelyin a settlement) that exceeds <strong>the</strong> cost of <strong>the</strong> legalservices. But in many cases poor individuals donot have <strong>the</strong> assets on-hand to pay <strong>the</strong> up-frontfees necessary to retain legal services in <strong>the</strong>private market (Yeazell 2006). Moreover, <strong>the</strong>irdisputes usually unfold with o<strong>the</strong>r poor peopleas defendants, and are mostly about division ofproperty ra<strong>the</strong>r than damages. It is unlikely that<strong>the</strong>re is a ‘deep pocket’ around that can be <strong>the</strong>target of a claim. For <strong>the</strong>se reasons, <strong>the</strong> solutionthat <strong>the</strong>ir claim is financed by o<strong>the</strong>rs — by <strong>the</strong>irlawyer <strong>for</strong> instance — is usually not available.That being said, <strong>the</strong>re may be situations wherefinancing of claims is an option, such as in <strong>the</strong>case of personal injury arising from road trafficaccidents, and this will increasingly be <strong>the</strong> caseat higher stages of development. To that end gov-33


ernments may consider to remove artificial barriersto <strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong> financing of claims, <strong>for</strong> instanceby changing <strong>the</strong> rules against contingencyfee arrangements (Kritzer 2004, Yeazell 2006),although this may prove to be a controversial issue.Ano<strong>the</strong>r alternative, which combines elements of<strong>the</strong> contingency fee system with a more traditionalcivil legal aid system, is <strong>the</strong> ‘contingency legal aidfund’ (CLAF) (Capper 2003). In a CLAF system,<strong>the</strong> government establishes a fund to subsidiselitigation by indigent civil plaintiffs. <strong>Law</strong>yers whorepresent such plaintiffs are reimbursed <strong>for</strong> a portionof <strong>the</strong>ir costs if <strong>the</strong>y lose. If <strong>the</strong>y win, on <strong>the</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong>y are required to contribute a portionof <strong>the</strong> damage award to replenish <strong>the</strong> fund.A CLAF system would place more burden on <strong>the</strong>public treasury than a system that relied on contingencyfees, but it would be less expensive thana traditional civil legal aid system. Similarly, whilea CLAF system would have less powerful incentiveeffects than a contingency fee system: cases witha low probability of winning look more attractive,and cases with a high probability of winning lookless attractive, under a CLAF system as comparedto a contingency fee system. Whe<strong>the</strong>r that is agood thing or a bad thing depends on <strong>the</strong> socialvalue we attach to expanding <strong>the</strong> opportunities <strong>for</strong>individuals with facially weak claims to have accessto a lawyer. CLAF may also be an attractive‘middle way’ <strong>for</strong> countries that have traditionallyrejected contingency fees, but are interested inexperimenting with market- or incentive-basedalternatives to traditional civil legal aid. It is alsopossible to use <strong>the</strong> same basic approach suggestedabove <strong>for</strong> emergency legal insurance:greater reliance on relatively small, communitybasedrepresentative organisations. In addition toproviding support <strong>for</strong> members who are facing alegal emergency, <strong>the</strong>se organisations could alsoprovide financial support <strong>for</strong> members who need tohire a legal professional to pursue a legal claim <strong>for</strong>damages against some o<strong>the</strong>r party; <strong>the</strong> claimant,if victorious, could <strong>the</strong>n pay back <strong>the</strong> organisation<strong>for</strong> fronting <strong>the</strong> money. Alternatively organisationslarge enough to retain <strong>the</strong>ir own legal servicescould ‘loan’ <strong>the</strong>ir legal representatives to membersin need without charge.The preceding discussion has focused primarilyon cases in which an individual’sability to access legal services confers benefitsprimarily on that individual. However, <strong>the</strong> privatebenefits that an individual may derive from effectiveaccess to <strong>the</strong> legal system may not alwaysbe equal to <strong>the</strong> social interest in providing suchaccess (Shavell 1997). In some cases, <strong>the</strong> socialresources — in terms of both time and money— that result from an individual’s pursuit of alegal claim may be very high, even though <strong>the</strong>costs to <strong>the</strong> individual are relatively low. In thosecases, individuals will have an incentive to ‘overconsume’legal and judicial resources. In o<strong>the</strong>rcases, and that is far more likely to be a problemin relation to <strong>the</strong> rights of <strong>the</strong> poor, individualpursuit of legal claims may confer more generalbenefits on a larger class of people, or on societygenerally. In those cases, individuals may havetoo little incentive to press <strong>the</strong>ir legal claims.There are three primary reasons why this mightoccur.First, each individual legal claim brought by aninjured victim against an injurer contributes to <strong>the</strong>general deterrence of unlawful conduct. The individualclaimant, however, does not internalie <strong>the</strong>full value of this deterrence benefit (Shavell 1997).Second, where an individual seeks a remedy thatinvolves <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m of an institution or <strong>the</strong> eliminationof a harmful unlawful practice, that remedy,like general deterrence, will typically benefit34


a much larger class of people. As a result, eachindividual’s incentive to pursue that systemicrelief may be too small.Third, each individual who pursues a legal claimmay influence <strong>the</strong> development of <strong>the</strong> underlyingsubstantive law. Comparative studies have foundthat this is true even in countries where, as a matterof official legal ideology, judges merely applypre-existing law to new disputes (MacCormick andSummers 1991, 1997). Even though an individuallitigant internalises some of <strong>the</strong> benefit of a favourablechange in <strong>the</strong> law, she typically will notinternalise <strong>the</strong> full social benefits of such changes.Thus, individuals have insufficiently strong incentivesto press <strong>for</strong> beneficial legal re<strong>for</strong>m (Landesand Posner 1979). Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, litigants whohave only occasional contact with <strong>the</strong> legal systemwill be at a disadvantage to entities that are‘repeat players’, because <strong>the</strong> latter will generallyhave a stronger incentive to influence <strong>the</strong> developmentof <strong>the</strong> law. This may put poor individuals ata systematic disadvantage relative to entrenchedinstitutions and elites (Galanter 1974).For <strong>the</strong>se and o<strong>the</strong>r reasons, <strong>the</strong> pursuit of legalclaims — and <strong>the</strong> investment in capable legalservice providers to advance <strong>the</strong>se claims — maybenefit many besides those directly involved.Where disputes have such ‘public goods’ characteristics,individual demand <strong>for</strong> legal services willbe too low from a social perspective. In <strong>the</strong>sesituations, re<strong>for</strong>ms that provide an incentive tosecure legal services specifically (as opposed toef<strong>for</strong>ts to redistribute income generally) may beappropriate.One approach to redressing this type of marketfailure would be <strong>for</strong> governments, NGOs, or internationaldonors to provide targeted legal assistancein cases where <strong>the</strong> individual pursuit of alegal claim is most likely to confer a public goodas well as a private benefit (Shavell 1997). Asecond approach to addressing this sort of marketfailure would be to empower local communityadvocacy groups and o<strong>the</strong>r representative civilsociety organisations (including, <strong>for</strong> example,public interest advocacy groups, labour unions,renters’ or landlords’ associations, and coalitionsof small business interests) to pursue legalclaims on behalf of <strong>the</strong>ir members. While <strong>the</strong>seorganisations may not be perfect representativesof collective or public interests, <strong>the</strong>y may have astronger incentive to pursue legal relief that hasbroad public benefits than does any one individual.An established community organisation isalso more likely to be a repeat player in <strong>the</strong> legalsystem, which means that it typically will have astronger incentive to pursue a long-term strategyof legal change. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, community-basedorganisations, while hardly perfect, are likelyto have better judgment than national governments,international donors, or o<strong>the</strong>r NGOs aboutwhat allocation of scarce legal aid resources willachieve <strong>the</strong> greatest collective benefit.These observations suggest three approachesto streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong> role of local civil societyorganisations. First, it is important to create aninstitutional environment in which such groupsare relatively easy to <strong>for</strong>m and sustain (NCLEPPhilippines 2007). Second, it may often be awise to empower organisations to pursue legalremedies on behalf of <strong>the</strong>ir members or<strong>the</strong> general public. Relaxing rules on who canbring a suit <strong>for</strong> example, by liberalising standingrequirements and expanding <strong>the</strong> availabilityof representative actions, two re<strong>for</strong>ms that <strong>the</strong>Indian Supreme Court has pioneered, may enablecommunity organisations to pursue publicinterest litigation even when no individual wouldhave a sufficient incentive to do so (Dembowski2000). Third, because local community organi-35


sations may make better decisions about how totarget scarce legal aid resources, it is often advisable<strong>for</strong> governments and international donorsto provide funding to <strong>the</strong>se local organisationsand allow <strong>the</strong>m to decide how to allocate <strong>the</strong>seresources. That suggestion must be tempered,however, with <strong>the</strong> recognition that corruptionand abuse by <strong>the</strong>se local organisations may beserious concerns. Thus, effective monitoring isessential. Finally, and more controversially, <strong>the</strong>incentives of claimants or legal service providersto pursue claims that serve <strong>the</strong> public good maybe streng<strong>the</strong>ned through <strong>the</strong> use of special damageawards and fee-shifting arrangements.The preceding discussion leads to <strong>the</strong> followinggeneral recommendations:• First, in <strong>the</strong> context of legal entitlements witha high private value, governments and donorsshould target <strong>the</strong>ir subsidies at those caseswhere individuals find <strong>the</strong>mselves in legalemergencies and self-insurance or privateinsurance are not viable options. Providingfree legal representation <strong>for</strong> indigent criminaldefendants is <strong>the</strong> most obvious example, but<strong>the</strong>re are o<strong>the</strong>r cases in this category as well.• Second, when legal aid resources are scarce,it makes sense to ration <strong>the</strong>se resources sothat legal aid is targeted primarily at caseswhere <strong>the</strong> pursuit of <strong>the</strong> individual legal claimis more likely to benefit a larger class of disempoweredindividuals: 1) disputes wheredeterrence of future wrongdoing is particularlyimportant; 2) ‘impact’ litigation that seeksbroad institutional re<strong>for</strong>m remedies or changesin <strong>the</strong> substantive law.• Third, governments and donors should encourageand facilitate <strong>the</strong> organisation of localgroups that can provide legal representation(or funding <strong>for</strong> legal representation) to <strong>the</strong>irmembers. In many cases, governments anddonors should funnel <strong>the</strong>ir legal insurancefunding through <strong>the</strong>se groups ra<strong>the</strong>r than tryingto reach individuals directly. Local, community-basedrepresentative groups, much like<strong>the</strong> rotating credit associations celebrated in<strong>the</strong> literature on micro-finance, allow individualsto pool <strong>the</strong>ir risk and provide <strong>the</strong>m with asource of financing in times of need. Theseorganisations also provide more effective monitoringand allocate resources more efficientlythan states or donor organisations.Reducing Transaction Costs:Wholesale Re<strong>for</strong>msThe preceding section concluded with an analysisof <strong>the</strong> situation where one lawsuit creates benefits<strong>for</strong> a large number of poor people. This is anexample of a more general strategy to look <strong>for</strong> approachesthat lead to economies of scale. Like <strong>the</strong>benefits of access to justice can spread over manypeople, <strong>the</strong>re are also approaches that reduce <strong>the</strong>costs of access to justice <strong>for</strong> many people at <strong>the</strong>same time. A typical example is <strong>the</strong> costs thatresult from complex and archaic procedures thatserve little or no useful function. It is often cheaperto eliminate <strong>the</strong> source of such costs ‘wholesale’than it would be to provide ‘retail’ assistance toindividuals who want to use <strong>the</strong> system. Thus,when <strong>the</strong> diagnosis of <strong>the</strong> problem is high transactioncosts of using <strong>the</strong> legal system, re<strong>for</strong>mersshould consider wholesale solutions as an alternative,or complement, to subsidised provision ofindividual-level legal services. Such solutions include:1) making <strong>the</strong> laws simpler, focusing accessto justice ef<strong>for</strong>ts on common problems <strong>the</strong> poor; 2)creating small claims courts with simplified proceduresthat do not require a lawyer’s assistance;and 3) allowing those with similar complaints tobring <strong>the</strong>ir cases up as a group or class. A fourthand more general strategy would be to find econo-36


mies of scale in <strong>the</strong> legal system.Consider as a simple example, access to basicin<strong>for</strong>mation about <strong>the</strong> law. As we sawin many developing countries simply finding outwhat <strong>the</strong> law is can be a time-consuming andcostly endeavour, because <strong>the</strong> laws are not availablein print, or only in a language not understoodby <strong>the</strong> poor. One way to ameliorate <strong>the</strong>setransaction cost barriers would be to provide orsubsidise legal service providers who are fluent inboth <strong>the</strong> national language and <strong>the</strong> local vernacular.This approach, however, would be extraordinarilyexpensive. A more sensible solution wouldbe to translate <strong>the</strong> law into all significant locallanguages, to provide user-friendly terminologyor explanatory notes <strong>for</strong> likely incomprehensibleterms and jargon, to disseminate it widely, to ensurethat law is administered (to <strong>the</strong> extent possible)in <strong>the</strong> language of <strong>the</strong> relevant region, andto provide centralised translation services wherethis is not possible (e.g. NCLEP Pakistan 2007,NCLEP Tanzania 2007, NCLEP Uganda 2007).While this set of approaches is not cost-free, it isa much cheaper way of reducing linguistic barriersto access than providing individual-level legalassistance. 5Standard Routes <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Most Urgent Legal NeedsOne of <strong>the</strong> values instilled in law students allover <strong>the</strong> world is that solutions to legal problemsshould be highly contextual, taking into accountevery aspect of <strong>the</strong> situation. This ideal is alsoreflected in <strong>the</strong> way law firms and courts tend tobe organised. A case is assigned to a lawyer, or toa judge, who spends as many hours on <strong>the</strong> caseas <strong>the</strong> case needs. Although o<strong>the</strong>r billing methodsexist, most lawyers are paid by <strong>the</strong> hour, sothat <strong>the</strong>y have fewer incentives than o<strong>the</strong>r similarservice providers to look <strong>for</strong> standardised solutionsto similar problems. Standardisation doesoccur in bigger law firms, but <strong>the</strong>se are not verylikely to serve <strong>the</strong> poor.Compare this to doctors and o<strong>the</strong>r healthcareproviders, who increasingly w<strong>ork</strong> from protocolsthat reflect <strong>the</strong> best treatment practices <strong>for</strong> commonailments. These protocols are in<strong>for</strong>med byresearch and make implied trade-offs betweenquality (risk) and costs. The protocols are availableon <strong>the</strong> Internet, so that clients can check<strong>the</strong>m, and hold <strong>the</strong>ir doctors accountable if necessary.Like people come to doctors with moreor less standard problems, many legal problemsof individuals are ra<strong>the</strong>r similar. Termination ofemployment, changes in land use or rented housingarrangements, splitting up of families, deathof parents, termination of cooperation betweenbusiness partners and expropriation <strong>for</strong> propertydevelopment are <strong>the</strong> most common transitionsin a life time. They tend to lead to similar problemswith division of property and redefiningrelationships in such a way that social capital ispreserved. Issues between husband and wife, betweenlandlord and tenant, between users of <strong>the</strong>same source of water, or between employer andemployee follow certain common patterns as well.This creates possibilities <strong>for</strong> economies of scale.Standard in<strong>for</strong>mation leaflets <strong>for</strong> clients can save<strong>the</strong> costs of intake and leave clients better in<strong>for</strong>med.Best practices <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> settlement processcan be designed. Rules of thumb <strong>for</strong> division ofproperty can be defined, if necessary with standardexceptions when common reasons <strong>for</strong> derogationfrom <strong>the</strong> more general rule occur. Tradeunions can specialise in employment issues, andleave family issues to o<strong>the</strong>r specialists.However, policy makers should also investigatewhy this standardisation does not happen spontaneously.One possible reason is that providersof justice services have little means to influ-37


ence o<strong>the</strong>rs in <strong>the</strong> supply chain to accept moreefficient settlement and litigation procedures.Their clients, often opponents in a conflict, arenot very likely to cooperate in order to find <strong>the</strong>most efficient process. The incentives on lawyers,who are in a unique position as professionalsbecause <strong>the</strong>y can directly create w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> eacho<strong>the</strong>r, are very different from those in a normalsupply chain. There, producers, distributors andclients all have <strong>the</strong> same incentives to cut <strong>the</strong>transaction costs, because <strong>the</strong>re is an exposureto outside competition. The incentives on judgesand o<strong>the</strong>r neutrals may also w<strong>ork</strong> against standardisation.They have no duty to <strong>the</strong> disputants tomake a trade-off between costs and quality when<strong>the</strong>y organise <strong>the</strong> process through <strong>the</strong>ir decisionson procedure, and in some legal systems <strong>the</strong>y aresupposed to leave <strong>the</strong> management of <strong>the</strong> procedureto <strong>the</strong> parties.These issues regarding <strong>the</strong> management of <strong>the</strong>justice supply chain have, as far as <strong>the</strong> W<strong>ork</strong>ingGroup could establish, not yet been studied indepth (Hadfield 2000 is one of <strong>the</strong> exceptions).An open question is, <strong>for</strong> instance, why legalservices to individuals tend to be per<strong>for</strong>med byindividual lawyers, or small partnerships, and notby bigger companies that offer standard services<strong>for</strong> common problems, such as is <strong>the</strong> case <strong>for</strong>banking and insurance. Ano<strong>the</strong>r issue is where<strong>the</strong> responsibility <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> design and improvementof procedures should be located: Is this primarily<strong>the</strong> task of <strong>the</strong> legislator, of <strong>the</strong> judiciary, or is<strong>the</strong>re a role here <strong>for</strong> bottom up processes as well?We now turn to this topic of improving <strong>the</strong> designof procedures Simplifying ProceduresAn attractive approach to reducing legal transactioncosts wholesale, ra<strong>the</strong>r than attempting tosubsidise <strong>the</strong>se costs on a retail basis, would beto simplify <strong>the</strong> substantive and procedural law.One essential step could be to allow individualsto advance <strong>the</strong>ir legal claims without representationin small claims courts or o<strong>the</strong>r morein<strong>for</strong>mal tribunals (Lopez-de-Silanes 2002,Buscaglia and Ulen 1997). Adopting this approachis probably not without costs: Simplifyinglaws so that <strong>the</strong>y can be understood and invokedby uneducated lay people may require makinglaws cruder, less nuanced, and less efficient,although some may argue that targeting lawsbetter to <strong>the</strong> problems of <strong>the</strong> poor may have <strong>the</strong>opposite effect. If <strong>the</strong> legislator has sufficientin<strong>for</strong>mation and background analysis regardingwhat constitute <strong>the</strong> most common concerns andgrievances of poor people and o<strong>the</strong>r disadvantagedgroups, <strong>the</strong> substantive legislation may betailored to be receptive to such grievances.There may be several layers within pieces oflegislation that aim at different target groupsensuring that principles of equality and nondiscriminationare adhered to, whilst on ano<strong>the</strong>rlevel <strong>the</strong> legislation is drafted in a sufficientlysophisticated manner to cater <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> needs <strong>for</strong>nuances and detail. Administering laws in smallclaims courts or in<strong>for</strong>mal tribunals entails dispensingwith some of <strong>the</strong> procedural safeguardsthat attend more <strong>for</strong>mal legal proceedings, and<strong>the</strong> adjudicators in such <strong>for</strong>ums may be lesscompetent. However, many of <strong>the</strong> legal issues ofpoor people are reasonably simple in legal terms<strong>the</strong> problem is that <strong>the</strong>y are met with overtly andunnecessary completed procedures that onlyw<strong>ork</strong> to exclude <strong>the</strong> poor from justice settlementmechanisms.One way of dealing with this is to provide peoplewith ‘simple’ and ‘sophisticated’ procedures nextto each o<strong>the</strong>r. Poor plaintiffs will <strong>the</strong>n be able tochoose <strong>the</strong> procedure <strong>the</strong>y find is most appropriateto <strong>the</strong>ir problem and circumstances. However,this requires clear consumer in<strong>for</strong>mation, andnecessitates designing ‘simple’ procedures that38


at least meet certain quality thresholds.None<strong>the</strong>less, legal and adjudicative simplificationmay drastically reduce <strong>the</strong> transactioncosts of access to justice <strong>for</strong> a very largenumber of potential consumers of justice services(NCLEP Tanzania 2007, NCLEP Uganda 2007).The net social welfare gains associated with thisstrategy may be much larger than <strong>the</strong> net gainsassociated with trying to provide every needy individualwith sufficient legal aid to navigate <strong>the</strong>complexities of a more ‘sophisticated’ legal andjudicial system (Galanter 1976, Hay, Shleifer andVishny 1996, Posner 1998).General <strong>for</strong>malistic court procedures may alsobe altered to accommodate poor people or peoplewho have had little contact with <strong>for</strong>mal statestructures be<strong>for</strong>e appearing in court. Archaicregulations regarding dress-codes, how to sit orstand, <strong>the</strong> set up of <strong>the</strong> court where <strong>the</strong> judgesand <strong>the</strong> officials of <strong>the</strong> court sit on a higher plateauthan <strong>the</strong> audience and <strong>the</strong> parties to <strong>the</strong>suit, use of official language without necessaryinterpretation into local languages are all featuresthat can easily be removed and interpretation canbe organised with little extra resources.A potential political difficulty with <strong>the</strong>se sorts ofwholesale institutional re<strong>for</strong>ms is that many of<strong>the</strong>m reduce <strong>the</strong> demand <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> services offeredby attorneys or o<strong>the</strong>r legal professionals; indeed,that is part of <strong>the</strong> point of such re<strong>for</strong>ms. Thus,even when wholesale transaction-cost reducingstrategies are efficient, <strong>the</strong>y may provoke politicalopposition. For example, Brazil recently establishedsmall claims courts in which individualscan appear without having to retain counsel.The Brazilian Bar Association opposed <strong>the</strong> provisionand is contesting <strong>the</strong> legality of this aspectof <strong>the</strong> small claims court system (Hammergren2007). Similarly, <strong>the</strong> bar association in Uruguaystrenuously objected to transaction-cost reducingre<strong>for</strong>ms that streamlined and expedited civiland criminal trials (Messick 1999). And whenPeru wanted to liberalise its property registrationsystem to make it more accessible to low-incomePeruvians, lawyers and notaries objected because<strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms eliminated <strong>the</strong> monopoly that<strong>the</strong> legal profession previously had on verifyingand registering property ownership (World Bank1997). In o<strong>the</strong>r cases, though, organised bar associationshave recognised <strong>the</strong> value of re<strong>for</strong>msto reduce aggregate transaction costs, and havebeen a powerful ally of pro-poor re<strong>for</strong>mers. It is<strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e important to cultivate <strong>the</strong> support of<strong>the</strong> legal profession when pursuing <strong>the</strong>se sorts ofre<strong>for</strong>ms.Bundling Claims: Class ActionsAno<strong>the</strong>r important situation in which <strong>the</strong> transactioncosts associated with individual-level legalservices may lead to failures in <strong>the</strong> legal servicesmarket involves situations is when many individualssuffer a relatively small injury from a commonor similar source. In such cases <strong>the</strong> aggregateinjury to social welfare may be large, but no individualhas sufficient incentives to incur <strong>the</strong> costsof securing <strong>the</strong> legal services necessary to seekredress of <strong>the</strong> injury. While it would be possibleto address this problem by providing subsidisedlegal services to every individual who might havea valid legal claim, this approach is extremely inefficient.An alternative approach is to authorisesome <strong>for</strong>m of aggregate multi-party or representativelitigation, so that a small number of legalservice providers can represent a large group ofsimilarly situated individual.One model <strong>for</strong> such litigation is <strong>the</strong> class actionmechanism widely used in <strong>the</strong> United States.While class actions have <strong>the</strong>ir flaws, <strong>the</strong> classaction device has been a powerful tool in expand-39


ing access to justice <strong>for</strong> disadvantaged groups in<strong>the</strong> United States (Bloom 2006). In <strong>the</strong> developingworld, class action suits have also producednotable successes <strong>for</strong> poor people in India, SouthAfrica, and elsewhere. Although class action suitsare less common in civil law jurisdictions, recentlysome civil law countries, including Brazil andIndonesia, have begun to experiment with authorsclass action suits <strong>for</strong> certain types of issues (Gidi2003). While <strong>the</strong>se re<strong>for</strong>ms have <strong>the</strong>ir problemsand detractors, <strong>the</strong>re is some evidence that <strong>the</strong>class action mechanism has improved access tojustice <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor. In Brazil, <strong>for</strong> example, classactions against municipal governments have successfullychallenged illegal taxes and illegal fareincreases <strong>for</strong> public busses. Brazilian plaintiffshave also successfully deployed class action litigationagainst private companies to redress masswrongs such as product defects, environmentaldamage, and abusive or deceptive marketingpractices (Gidi 2003).This is not to say that U.S., Indian, or Brazilianapproach to class action litigation is <strong>the</strong> rightmodel. Ra<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> point is that when large numbersof poor people are victims of <strong>the</strong> same orsimilar legal injury, it is prudent to design somesort of mechanism through which <strong>the</strong>y can pursue<strong>the</strong>ir claims collectively, ra<strong>the</strong>r than requiringeach potential claimant to pursue her own claimseparately. That latter approach entails ei<strong>the</strong>r awholesale denial of access to justice (if few or nopotential claimants are able to af<strong>for</strong>d adequatelegal representation) or massive costs (if largenumbers of claimants pursue <strong>the</strong>ir individualclaims separately). One attractive political featureof expanding access to multi-party representativelitigation is that, in contrast to transaction-costreduction strategies that reduce demand <strong>for</strong> legalservices, expanding <strong>the</strong> availability of collectivelitigation devices tends to increase <strong>the</strong> demand<strong>for</strong> legal services and <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e should appeal to<strong>the</strong> legal profession (at least its more entrepreneurialmembers). Political opposition to this sortof re<strong>for</strong>m is more likely to come from potentialtargets of class suits, including government agencies,municipalities, and large corporations.An alternative bundling mechanism to class actionsthat also supports a controlled handlingof large numbers of similar (tort) claims is <strong>the</strong>establishment of a compensation fund. Compensationfunds usually provide fixed amounts ofcompensation to injured parties in cases where<strong>the</strong> rules of (tort) law and/or <strong>the</strong> institutional legalinfrastructure function inadequately or functionnot at all, e.g. in post-war and post-disaster situations.Simple, user-friendly application procedures,<strong>for</strong> instance run by NGO’s in collaborationwith <strong>the</strong> local community and authorities, couldfacilitate people in need of basic subsistence torebuild <strong>the</strong>ir lives with monetary and non-monetarymeans at relatively low transaction costs.O<strong>the</strong>r Ways to Reduce Costs of Access WholesaleStandardisation of settlement and negotiationprocesses, improving procedures, and bundlingclaims are but examples of ways to reduce transactioncosts wholesale and to raise <strong>the</strong> quality ofprocedures and outcomes. A substantial proportionof <strong>the</strong> costs of access to justice comes from <strong>the</strong>process of finding, establishing and substantiating<strong>the</strong> facts. How extensive fact-finding should be,however, is a design issue <strong>for</strong> procedures, that isseldom addressed explicitly. There is an obvioustrade-off between <strong>the</strong> costs of <strong>the</strong> registration proceduresand processes to settle disputes or to en<strong>for</strong>cerights and <strong>the</strong> costs of error if <strong>the</strong> wrong factsare established. Requiring unnecessary documentsor evidence can be a serious barrier to access.The issue of fact-finding is again related to <strong>the</strong>applicable legal criteria and <strong>the</strong> way <strong>the</strong>y are pro-40


duced. In most legal systems, <strong>the</strong> rules of privatelaw that determine <strong>the</strong> outcome of <strong>the</strong> most commondisputes of <strong>the</strong> poor are ra<strong>the</strong>r open ended.Both in common law and in civil law countriescase law is supposed to generate more guidanceover time, but deciding and publishing cases oneby one is not <strong>the</strong> only — and often not <strong>the</strong> mostefficient — way to procedure criteria that canhelp people to settle disputes. Neutral institutionslike government commissions, committeesof judges, or academics can play a useful rolehere. An example is damage scheduling, whichguides <strong>the</strong> disputants and <strong>the</strong> judge when <strong>the</strong>yhave to establish <strong>the</strong> value of a personal injuryclaim without binding <strong>the</strong>m. This is very commonin European legal systems that have to dealwith personal injury claims. Such criteria mayreduce <strong>the</strong> costs of fact-finding substantially, canincrease transparency of <strong>the</strong> outcomes, and makesettlement easier to achieve (Bovbjerg et al.). Oneof <strong>the</strong> key issues here is that <strong>the</strong>se rules act asa presumption, without sacrificing <strong>the</strong> possibilityto tailor <strong>the</strong> result to <strong>the</strong> specific circumstances,thus saving decision costs without a correspondingincrease in <strong>the</strong> costs of error (Schauer 1991,Kaplow 1992).Ano<strong>the</strong>r example in which wholesale re<strong>for</strong>mmakes more sense than subsidising individual legaltransactions involves <strong>the</strong> legal documentationof common transactions — such as sale, rental,and employment contracts — as well as commonlegal documents like wills, title registrations, andgovernment claim applications. Securing <strong>the</strong> assistancenecessary to draft legally valid versionsof <strong>the</strong>se and o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>mal documents can be expensive.As a result, poor people may simply <strong>for</strong>ego<strong>the</strong> activity in question (which is inefficient),may <strong>for</strong>ego legal documentation (which is risky),or, in <strong>the</strong> case of transactions with a more sophisticatedparty, may rely on documents provided bythat party (which might lead to exploitation).One solution to this problem is to provideretail legal aid services, provided ei<strong>the</strong>r bylawyers or paralegals. The advantage of this approachis that <strong>the</strong> legal service can be tailored to<strong>the</strong> individual client’s needs. The disadvantage,however, is that this client-by-client approach isextremely expensive. Ano<strong>the</strong>r drawback of oneon-oneservices especially in commonly occurringlegal needs is <strong>the</strong> non-profitability of <strong>the</strong> service<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> larger community. An alternative strategymight be <strong>for</strong> local lawyers, in collaboration withcivil society groups and o<strong>the</strong>r community-basedorganisations like local councils, chambers ofcommerce, banks, among o<strong>the</strong>rs, among o<strong>the</strong>rs,to draft and disseminate standard-<strong>for</strong>m documents<strong>for</strong> common legal transactions and provideeducation and outreach explaining <strong>the</strong> significanceof <strong>the</strong> documents. This approach sacrificesindividual tailoring in <strong>the</strong> interests of exploitingeconomies of scale. However, it facilitates sharing<strong>the</strong> benefits of legal services amongst groups ofcitizens in comparable situations at lower costs.The bottom-line message is: The inability of poorpeople to access <strong>the</strong> legal system is frequently<strong>the</strong> result of <strong>the</strong> transaction costs associated with<strong>the</strong> pursuit of valid legal claims. It is often <strong>the</strong>case that many individuals face similar transactioncosts arising from a common source, orwould have to pay similar transaction costs toseek redress of a common legal injury or problem.In <strong>the</strong> presence of such aggregate or redundantlegal transaction costs, re<strong>for</strong>mers should try toaddress <strong>the</strong> problem at <strong>the</strong> wholesale level, ra<strong>the</strong>rthan focusing exclusively on <strong>the</strong> provision ofretail-level legal aid services or neutral disputeresolution to individuals. Wholesale re<strong>for</strong>m strategiesinclude both re<strong>for</strong>ms that eliminate <strong>the</strong>source of significant legal transaction costs <strong>for</strong>large numbers of individuals (e.g., legal stand-41


ardisation and simplification) and also re<strong>for</strong>msthat enable large numbers of potential claimantsto pool <strong>the</strong>ir resources to pursue <strong>the</strong>ir commonlegal interests ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>for</strong>cing <strong>the</strong>m all to pursue<strong>the</strong>ir individual claims separately (e.g., classaction mechanisms).Improving In<strong>for</strong>mal and CustomaryDispute Resolution 6Most poor people — especially <strong>the</strong> poorest of <strong>the</strong>poor — have little or no contact with <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mallegal system, and are not likely to do so even ifall aspects of <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agendaare implemented. They instead seek justice fromcustomary law (which may be highly <strong>for</strong>malisedand is sometimes officially recognised by <strong>the</strong>state system) and from in<strong>for</strong>mal norms, practices,religions and institutions. For example, in sub-Saharan Africa, customary land tenure law coversroughly 75 percent of land and in some countries,such as Mozambique and Ghana, over 90percent of land transactions are governed by customarylaw (Wojkowska 2006). In urban shantytownsin Columbia, squatters who cannot rely on<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal system because of <strong>the</strong>ir illegal statushave established in<strong>for</strong>mal urban justice systemsto deal with disputes and provide basic services(Faundez 2006). Traditional and modern civilsociety institutions continue to play an importantrole in local dispute settlement in Afghanistan.Traditional decision making assemblies are estimatedto account <strong>for</strong> more than 80 percent ofcases settled throughout Afghanistan (AfghanistanHDR 2007). These examples are merelyisolated illustrations of a much more pervasivephenomenon: <strong>the</strong> predominance of non-state justicesystems as <strong>the</strong> primary mode of dispute resolutionin <strong>the</strong> lived experience of <strong>the</strong> overwhelmingmajority of <strong>the</strong> world’s poor.One element of <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment’s agenda,of course, is to enable more poor people tomake <strong>the</strong> transition from <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector to<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal, while at <strong>the</strong> same time integratinguseful norms and practices from in<strong>for</strong>mal or customarysystems. These approaches are discussedin detail in <strong>the</strong> chapters prepared by <strong>the</strong> Commission’sw<strong>ork</strong>ing groups on property rights, labour,and business, and we will, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, not focuson <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>malization of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector or onfacilitating <strong>the</strong> transition from <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sectorto <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal. Formalization is not always possible,however, and indeed, not always desirable, as<strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups discuss in detail in <strong>the</strong>irchapters within this volume. In<strong>for</strong>mal justice systemsmay be more culturally familiar, more easilyaccessible, cheaper, and better tailored to localcircumstances than <strong>the</strong> state-run legal system.Poor people may also be more willing to use nonstatejustice systems because of a general distrustor fear of <strong>for</strong>mal state institutions, including<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal justice system (NCLEP Uganda 2007).For <strong>the</strong>se and o<strong>the</strong>r reasons, many countries haveopted to <strong>for</strong>mally recognise, or tacitly accept, <strong>the</strong>legitimacy of customary law in certain geographicregions or substantive areas. And some systemsare <strong>for</strong>mally integrated in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal legal systemand reflected in substantive legislation and <strong>the</strong>structure of <strong>the</strong> judiciary. Regulations have alsobeen enacted to provide <strong>for</strong>mal procedures <strong>for</strong>what legal system to chose and <strong>for</strong> how far <strong>the</strong>customary system may reach in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal judiciaryand justice system. In<strong>for</strong>mal or customarysystems, of course, have serious problems, and itwould be a mistake to romanticize or glamorize<strong>the</strong>m. In<strong>for</strong>mal and customary law can be oppressiveto women. They are almost totally excludedfrom participating in <strong>the</strong> decision making ofjirgas/shuras resulting in serious consequences<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir status and <strong>the</strong> protection of <strong>the</strong>ir rights(Afghanistan HDR 2007). In<strong>for</strong>mal systems may42


also exclude o<strong>the</strong>r disadvantaged social groups,may perpetuate <strong>the</strong> power of local elites andstifle dissent, and may be unsuited to rapideconomic development (NCLEP Uganda 2007).Just as poor communities may find it difficult toaccess <strong>for</strong>mal justice institutions, marginalizedmembers of poor communities may find it difficultto achieve equal access to <strong>the</strong> institutionsof customary or in<strong>for</strong>mal justice (NCLEP India2007, NCLEP Philippines 2007). None<strong>the</strong>less,despite <strong>the</strong>se problems, re<strong>for</strong>mers must acknowledgethat in many situations replacing in<strong>for</strong>mal orcustomary justice systems with <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal legalor bureaucratic institutions of <strong>the</strong> state is ei<strong>the</strong>rimpossible or would do more harm than good.There<strong>for</strong>e, alongside programmes to improve<strong>the</strong> state justice systems, re<strong>for</strong>mers should seekout opportunities <strong>for</strong> strategic interventions thatimprove <strong>the</strong> operation of in<strong>for</strong>mal or customaryjustice systems and facilitate <strong>the</strong> efficient integrationof <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>mal systems.Ultimately, re<strong>for</strong>ms and improvements to <strong>the</strong>non-state justice system must emerge ‘bottomup’from <strong>the</strong> participants in that system. Whilea government’s role in facilitating re<strong>for</strong>m of nonstatejustice systems is necessarily limited, itcan (perhaps in collaboration with internationaldonors w<strong>ork</strong>ing through government) take actionsto influence <strong>the</strong> development of non-statejustice systems. We may group <strong>the</strong>m under fourcategories: education and awareness campaigns;tailored legal aid services; targeted constraints,and structuring institutional relationships.Education and Awareness CampaignsEmpowering <strong>the</strong> poor to demand changes in <strong>the</strong>customary system is <strong>the</strong> first approach. Re<strong>for</strong>merscan encourage trans<strong>for</strong>mation from within simplyby providing in<strong>for</strong>mation about individuals’ legalrights under <strong>the</strong> constitution and about <strong>the</strong> normsof <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal legal system. In Bangladesh, <strong>for</strong>example, <strong>the</strong> Constitution <strong>for</strong>bids <strong>the</strong> practice o<strong>for</strong>al divorce, but in poor rural communities, <strong>the</strong>practice is still widespread. A Bangladeshi NGOfound that simply in<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>the</strong> members of localcustomary courts that oral divorce was <strong>for</strong>biddenby <strong>the</strong> constitution substantially reduced <strong>the</strong>practice. More generally, this NGO found that itwas possible to introduce norms from nationallaw into community deliberations and mediationpractices o<strong>the</strong>rwise based on customary law andtraditional norms (Golub 2000).Although this may be an exceptional case,education and awareness-raising campaignsmay have long term effects on <strong>the</strong> evolution ofcustomary law systems. This effect may be particularlypowerful if educational ef<strong>for</strong>ts are coupledwith improved access to <strong>the</strong> state system as analternative to <strong>the</strong> customary system. Customary legalofficials who want to retain <strong>the</strong>ir authority may<strong>the</strong>n feel some competitive pressure to modify<strong>the</strong> norms of <strong>the</strong> customary system to align <strong>the</strong>mmore closely with those of <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal system. Educationef<strong>for</strong>ts are not likely to reap visible shorttermbenefits, but in <strong>the</strong> longer term <strong>the</strong>y mayeffect significant change in cultural practices.A variant of <strong>the</strong> education-oriented approach isto provide in<strong>for</strong>mation on how o<strong>the</strong>r customarycourts have resolved similar disputes. Implementingschemes that let customary officials anddisputants in customary systems know how o<strong>the</strong>rcustomary courts have resolved similar issuesmay encourage consistency, limit abuse, and allow<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> gradual evolution of <strong>the</strong> customarysystem. This is not to say that customary legalsystems should be converted into common lawstyle courts with binding precedent. Ra<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong>suggestion is that in<strong>for</strong>mation sharing not onlyabout <strong>the</strong> norms of <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal legal system, butalso about <strong>the</strong> norms adopted by o<strong>the</strong>r custom-43


ary or in<strong>for</strong>mal systems, may improve <strong>the</strong> overallfunctioning of <strong>the</strong> system and empower poor peopleto challenge customary practices that seemlike arbitrary abuses of power.Tailored Legal Aid ServicesMost government and donor sponsored ef<strong>for</strong>ts toprovide more legal services to <strong>the</strong> poor emphasiseaccess to <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal legal system. Hence,a significant fraction of legal aid resources aretargeted at subsidising lawyers or reducing costsassociated with using <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal court system.But as it turns out, many poor people tend torely on in<strong>for</strong>mal or customary justice systems. In<strong>the</strong>ory, <strong>the</strong>se alternatives may be more familiarand accessible; but in practice, many poor people— particularly women, young people, and membersof o<strong>the</strong>r disadvantaged groups — may alsofind it difficult and intimidating to navigate <strong>the</strong>customary system. These vulnerable individualsmay also be subject to abuses by <strong>the</strong> local eliteswho administer traditional justice systems.Re<strong>for</strong>mers should, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, consider targetinglegal aid resources and legal service providerswho can help poor people deal with both <strong>the</strong>customary and <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal state system. Theparalegal programme in Sierra Leone discussedearlier is exemplary in this regard (Maru 2006).These paralegals have a basic training in <strong>for</strong>mallaw, but <strong>the</strong>y are also drawn from <strong>the</strong> local communityand are familiar with local traditions andcustomary law. They can <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e assist clientswith <strong>the</strong> non-state justice system. They can alsomonitor abuses, and are better positioned to adviseclients on when <strong>the</strong>y should threaten to takea dispute to <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal state system. Particularlyin light of <strong>the</strong> fact that markets <strong>for</strong> representationservices <strong>for</strong> non-state justice institutions are typicallythin or non-existent, legal aid resources maybe especially productive when focused on subsidisingthis sort of representation.Targeted Constraints on In<strong>for</strong>mal JusticeThe most straight<strong>for</strong>ward strategy <strong>for</strong> trying toreap <strong>the</strong> benefits of non-state justice while avoidingits flaws is to accept (<strong>for</strong>mally or tacitly) <strong>the</strong>legitimacy of non-state justice systems withincertain limits, but to strategically and aggressivelyintervene to require <strong>the</strong> non-state systemto respect certain fundamental norms that mighto<strong>the</strong>rwise conflict with traditional practices. Thatis, instead of attempting to displace or <strong>for</strong>malize<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal system entirely, government re<strong>for</strong>mersmight selectively impose a relatively smallnumber of especially important norms on <strong>the</strong> customarysystem.This approach is appealing because it seems toreflect a reasonable compromise between <strong>the</strong>interest in preserving and promoting non-statedispute resolution and <strong>the</strong> interest in respectingfundamental constitutional principles and humanrights norms. This proposed compromise, however,immediately raises <strong>the</strong> question of exactlywhich norms are so fundamental that <strong>the</strong>y musttake precedence over in<strong>for</strong>mal or customary practices.Because this question implicates <strong>the</strong> appropriatedesign of <strong>for</strong>mal laws on topics includingproperty, labour, and business activity, ourchapter does not cover this aspect of <strong>the</strong> problemin detail. It is worth emphasising, however, that<strong>the</strong> most prominent and difficult set of questionsconcerning <strong>the</strong> degree to which <strong>for</strong>mal law shouldtrump in<strong>for</strong>mal law concerns <strong>the</strong> status of womenand domestic relations.Despite <strong>the</strong> fact that many customary systemsclaim that <strong>the</strong> subordination of women is consistentwith traditional cultural practices, this is onearea where <strong>the</strong> state should be more aggressivein limiting <strong>the</strong>ir authority. Taking a strong standagainst gender discrimination in customary sys-44


tems is important both <strong>for</strong> intrinsic moral reasons— reflected in <strong>the</strong> human rights principles laidout in <strong>the</strong> Convention <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Elimination of AllForms of Discrimination Against Women — and<strong>for</strong> pragmatic economic reasons. This is in lightof <strong>the</strong> growing body of research that genderequality and women’s empowerment fosters sustainableeconomic growth and promotes healthand education.South Africa and Tanzania both offer powerfulrecent examples of cases where <strong>the</strong> state hasrecognised <strong>the</strong> legitimacy of customary law up toa point, but has required that customary systemschange to respect <strong>the</strong> equal rights and status ofwomen. In South Africa, NGOs successfully lobbied<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> passage of a ‘Recognition of CustomaryMarriages Act’ that <strong>for</strong>mally recognised marriagesconcluded in accordance of customary law,but only if customary law provided <strong>for</strong> equality ofhusband and wife in terms of status, decisionmakingauthority, property ownership, and childcustody (Centre <strong>for</strong> Applied Legal Studies 2002).Tanzania has enacted two Land Acts that confer<strong>for</strong>mal recognition on customary title, but alsomandate <strong>the</strong> elimination of customary practicesthat discriminate against women with respectto land ownership (Ikdahl et al. 2005, Tsikata2003). Nei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> South African nor <strong>the</strong> Tanzanianlaws have been implemented perfectly, andcustomary gender discrimination is still a pervasiveproblem in both countries, but <strong>the</strong>se experimentsnone<strong>the</strong>less suggest that it is possible toenact re<strong>for</strong>m built around a political compromise:<strong>for</strong>mal recognition of customary law in exchange<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> rejection of certain customary norms thatare repugnant to principles of non-discriminationand gender equality.Ano<strong>the</strong>r lesson of both <strong>the</strong> South African andTanzanian experiences is that <strong>the</strong>se sorts of re<strong>for</strong>mstrategies cannot be imposed immediatelyfrom <strong>the</strong> top down. Where cultural practices anddiscriminatory attitudes are deeply entrenched,successful legislative re<strong>for</strong>m requires sustainedconsultation, lobbying, and political organisingef<strong>for</strong>ts. Also, in some cases <strong>the</strong> pursuit of genderequity goals might need to be tempered bypragmatic considerations, and it might be betterto pursue a gradual re<strong>for</strong>m strategy that starts bytargeting only <strong>the</strong> most extreme <strong>for</strong>ms of genderdiscrimination, and <strong>the</strong>n progressively expanding<strong>the</strong> scope of this anti-discrimination principle. As<strong>the</strong> example in Box 2 shows, a complex legal universegoverns <strong>the</strong> legal position of poor women inmany developing countries. This example fur<strong>the</strong>rilluminates <strong>the</strong> effect of legal regimes in <strong>the</strong> fieldof inheritance and property rights of women andits effects on <strong>the</strong> prevalence of and societal situationwith regard to HIV/AIDS.While <strong>the</strong> implementation strategy will vary bycountry, targeted interventions to eliminate discriminatorypractices — particularly gender-baseddiscrimination — should be a prerequisite towidespread recognition or acceptance of customarydispute resolution systems.Structuring Institutional RelationshipsThe government can also influence access tojustice in non-state institutions by structuring<strong>the</strong> institutional relationship between <strong>the</strong> stateand non-state justice systems. One basic issue<strong>the</strong> government must consider is whe<strong>the</strong>r to giveone justice system exclusive jurisdiction over aparticular class of disputes, or whe<strong>the</strong>r disputantshave <strong>the</strong> option of choosing between differentsystems. (The absence of choice may be de jure— as when <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal law gives customary courtsin a particular area have exclusive jurisdictionover family relations or property disputes — or defacto — as when <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal court system is so45


Box 2 Coping with Legal Pluralism in Relation to Women’s Rightsin EthiopiaIn <strong>the</strong> Amhara region in Ethiopia, photographs of bothhusband and wife are required on <strong>the</strong> land title. Theprovision also restricts one spouse from selling or inany o<strong>the</strong>r way transfer <strong>the</strong> property without <strong>the</strong> knowledgeof <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r. This also reduces confusion that mayoccur at <strong>the</strong> death of one spouse. Although Ethiopia isquite advanced from a <strong>for</strong>mal legal perspective, <strong>the</strong>issue of women’s inheritance and property rights is stillcomplex. This is demonstrated <strong>for</strong> instance through <strong>the</strong>inter-relationship between <strong>the</strong> HIV/AIDS epidemic andwomen’s property and inheritance rights. Comparatively,a ten-country study on women’s inheritance rightsin sub-Saharan Africa suggests that unequal housing,property and inheritance rights increase women’svulnerability to HIV, because it is, in part, why womenremain in abusive marriages. Moreover women areoften blamed <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> deaths of <strong>the</strong>ir husbands and subsequently<strong>for</strong>ced from <strong>the</strong> household and left destitute.If <strong>the</strong>y remain in <strong>the</strong> household, <strong>the</strong>y are treated asservants or are married off to <strong>the</strong> fa<strong>the</strong>r, uncle, bro<strong>the</strong>ror ano<strong>the</strong>r close male relative — a practice known as“wife inheritance.”To address <strong>the</strong> issue of HIV and women’s inheritanceand property rights an initiative was launched. Theaim was to build <strong>the</strong> capacity of <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>maljustice systems, to generate individual and collectiveaction and to empower women in gaining equaltreatment in owning and inheriting property. A comprehensiveanalysis of <strong>the</strong> legal framew<strong>ork</strong> was carriedout which included a review of <strong>the</strong> statutory, civil andcustomary laws. The study provided a solid empiricalfoundation and underlined <strong>the</strong> strength of Ethiopianlaw. However, <strong>the</strong> substantive laws are not being appliedor en<strong>for</strong>ced. This is a result of a number of factors,including lack of awareness, lack of en<strong>for</strong>cementand ineffectiveness of <strong>the</strong> court system. Additionalchallenges include a lengthy and costly legal process,which most Ethiopians cannot af<strong>for</strong>d, cultural barriers,free legal services are not yet readily available; <strong>the</strong> fearof being shunned and stigmatised by both family andsociety; and conflicting laws which cause confusion ordiscrimination against women.The conflict between religious law and constitutionallaw has also come to <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>e. It stems from a clausein <strong>the</strong> constitution which recognises <strong>the</strong> adjudicationof personal and family matters under religiousor customary law, if both parties agree. Article 34(5)of <strong>the</strong> constitution states [on Marital, Personal andFamily Rights], ‘This Constitution shall not preclude<strong>the</strong> adjudication of disputes relating to personal andfam-ily laws in accordance with religious or customarylaws, with <strong>the</strong> consent of <strong>the</strong> parties to <strong>the</strong> dispute.’The conflict arises out of provisions in <strong>the</strong> Shariá lawthat contradict <strong>the</strong> terms set <strong>for</strong>th in <strong>the</strong> constitution.In reality, women are sometimes coerced into ‘consenting’by pressure from family or society. Although <strong>the</strong>sechallenges exist, Ethiopia is surpassing neighbouringcountries in <strong>the</strong> sense that <strong>the</strong>y do not need to createnew laws or re<strong>for</strong>m archaic ones. Initiatives and campaignshave been set in motion to counteract some of<strong>the</strong> problems and to respond to <strong>the</strong> challenges that aredemonstrating encouraging signs.expensive and inaccessible that customary lawis <strong>the</strong> only af<strong>for</strong>dable option.) Some have arguedthat integrating <strong>the</strong> customary system of disputeresolution into <strong>the</strong> mainstream legal system maybe an effective way to import desirable features of<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal system — including norms of genderequality and regularity — into <strong>the</strong> more accessiblecustomary system (NCLEP Uganda 2007).O<strong>the</strong>rs praise NGO ef<strong>for</strong>ts that have not focusedon a <strong>for</strong>mal integration of <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>malsystems (Golub 2007), such as <strong>the</strong> Bangladeshiprogrammes that have taken up <strong>the</strong> issue of legalempowerment <strong>for</strong> women (UNDP 2002). Ra<strong>the</strong>r,some of <strong>the</strong>se ef<strong>for</strong>ts have used <strong>the</strong> threat or realityof litigation (that is, <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal system) as anincentive <strong>for</strong> resistant or recalcitrant parties to46


participate in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal system and <strong>for</strong> suchparties to honour agreements <strong>the</strong>y have made. Thede facto impact has been to increase women’spower and well-being in in<strong>for</strong>mal systems that arevery gradually becoming less gender-biased.When <strong>the</strong>re is overlapping jurisdiction betweenlegal systems, a second issue arises:What should <strong>the</strong> rules be <strong>for</strong> choosing a <strong>for</strong>umand selecting <strong>the</strong> appropriate law to apply? Althoughone must be cautious in offering conclusiveanswers to <strong>the</strong>se general questions, a usefulgeneral presumption is that individuals shouldalways be able to opt into <strong>the</strong> state system in <strong>the</strong>early stages of a dispute, and <strong>the</strong>y should be ableto challenge decisions of <strong>the</strong> non-state systemthat are repugnant to fundamental human rightsprinciples. However, disputants who have electedto have a dispute resolved through <strong>the</strong> customarysystem should not be able to seek to undo anadverse judgment by re-litigating <strong>the</strong> dispute in<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal court system. These are basic principlestypically applied to ADR systems, and while<strong>the</strong>y may not be universally applicable, <strong>the</strong>y tendto promote efficiency, fairness, and healthy institutionalcompetition.4. Improving Access toJustice in <strong>the</strong> GovernmentBureaucracyThe Nature of <strong>the</strong> ProblemThe preceding section focused on access to <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mal (adjudicative) legal system and to in<strong>for</strong>maljustice mechanisms. But courts and out-of-courtfacilities are not <strong>the</strong> only institutions that en<strong>for</strong>ceindividual rights and resolve disputes. A greatdeal of such w<strong>ork</strong> is done by public bureaucracies,especially in <strong>the</strong> context of governmentregulation and service delivery, do a great dealof such w<strong>ork</strong>. Often <strong>the</strong> first (and sometimes <strong>the</strong>only) line of defence individuals have againstgovernment abuses and threatening or already encounteredinjustices from neighbours, <strong>the</strong> widercommunity or companies is through <strong>the</strong> bureaucraticsystem. If that system is not adequatelyaccessible <strong>for</strong> and responsive to <strong>the</strong> needs andinterests of poor individuals, <strong>the</strong>n it will not bepossible to legally empower <strong>the</strong> poor throughbureaucratic means. There<strong>for</strong>e, it is important toconsider <strong>the</strong> problem of access to bureaucraticjustice.One of <strong>the</strong> most important public bureaucracies,and <strong>the</strong> one which has great impact on <strong>the</strong> livesof many poor communities, is <strong>the</strong> police <strong>for</strong>ce.Public order and security are essential publicgoods, and a well-functioning law en<strong>for</strong>cementapparatus is necessary to provide individuals witha stable and orderly living environment and toprotect <strong>the</strong>m from violence and exploitation. Yetall too often <strong>the</strong> police not only do not provideadequate protection to vulnerable communities,but are <strong>the</strong>mselves perpetrators of violence andexploitation (Anderson 2003).In addition to law en<strong>for</strong>cement, state bureaucra-47


cies (including local authorities) are also responsible<strong>for</strong> providing a variety of o<strong>the</strong>r services,including clean water, health care, education,transportation, infrastructure, and social insurance.The degree to which <strong>the</strong>se and o<strong>the</strong>r servicesshould be supplied by <strong>the</strong> state ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong>market is a subject of considerable controversy,and not a matter on which a position is takenhere. Even when <strong>the</strong>se services are supplied in acompetitive market, it is almost always a marketthat is regulated by some public bureaucracy.Indeed, in most countries <strong>the</strong> provision of accessto a competitive market is — perhaps paradoxically— <strong>the</strong> responsibility of government regulatoryagencies.Yet all of <strong>the</strong>se public bureaucracies may bevulnerable to a variety of ‘government failures’,analogous in some respects to <strong>the</strong> ‘market failures’discussed earlier. The great variety of governmentfailures can be grouped into three majorcategories: malfeasance, underper<strong>for</strong>mance, andincompetence.‘Malfeasance’ is <strong>the</strong> tendency of bureaucrats,or bureaucratic organisations, to abuse <strong>the</strong>irpower to pursue illegitimate goals. The mostwell-known and comprehensively studied <strong>for</strong>m ofbureaucratic malfeasance in poor countries is, ofcourse, corruption (Shleifer and Vishny 1993).Public officials may demand bribes, may showfavouritism to family or friends, or may use <strong>the</strong>irpower vindictively against personal enemies.Powerful incumbent politicians may also view<strong>the</strong> bureaucracy as a tool <strong>for</strong> entrenching <strong>the</strong>irown power ra<strong>the</strong>r than a means <strong>for</strong> improvingpublic welfare. Whatever <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of malfeasance,<strong>the</strong> results <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor are fairly similar:deprivation of services, of (avenues to) sharedpower, and of security. These problems are pervasiveand much discussed throughout <strong>the</strong> developingworld. Malfeasance may also take moresubtle <strong>for</strong>ms. For example, even well-meaningbureaucrats may be prone to subconsciousprejudices resulting in a continuous neglect ofcertain interests or measures with unintendeddiscriminatory effects <strong>for</strong> certain groups. Also,when certain groups are more effective at mobilisingresources to influence bureaucratic decision-making,public decisions may be distortedin favour of <strong>the</strong>se groups, even if <strong>the</strong> bureaucraticdecision-makers are not consciously biased,and even if <strong>the</strong>se interest groups are acting legallyand in good faith.The second category of bureaucratic failure,‘underper<strong>for</strong>mance’, refers to <strong>the</strong> tendencyof even well-meaning bureaucrats to pursue <strong>the</strong>irmissions with a socially insufficient level of ef<strong>for</strong>t(Bueno de Mesquita and Stephenson 2007). Thebasic problem is that <strong>the</strong> rewards a bureaucratreceives are imperfectly correlated to how hardshe w<strong>ork</strong>s or how well she per<strong>for</strong>ms. As a result,bureaucrats may be slow to complete tasks or respondto inquiries, and may have weak incentivesto figure out how to improve <strong>the</strong> overall efficiencyof <strong>the</strong> system, preferring to rely on pre-existingapproaches to new problems ra<strong>the</strong>r than puttingin <strong>the</strong> time and ef<strong>for</strong>t to come up with betterones. Ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>m of underper<strong>for</strong>mance thatderives from <strong>the</strong> same basic incentive problem isinsufficient bureaucratic responsiveness to consumerinput or consumer complaints. Even hardw<strong>ork</strong>ing,public-spirited bureaucrats may becomedemoralized and give up if <strong>the</strong>y feel like mostmembers of <strong>the</strong>ir organisation are more interestedin leisure than in innovation.Third, bureaucratic organisations may simplylack <strong>the</strong> competence or capacity to achieve <strong>the</strong>irassigned tasks, even when <strong>the</strong> bureaucrats <strong>the</strong>mselvesare well-motivated (Huber and McCarty2004). Bureaucratic competence depends ona variety of factors, including <strong>the</strong> talent level of48


<strong>the</strong> individual bureaucrats, budgetary resources,<strong>the</strong> design of bureaucratic institutions and procedures,and appropriate feedback and accountabilitymechanisms. Where some or all of <strong>the</strong>seare deficient, government bureaucracies will notbe successful.Where <strong>the</strong> government bureaucracies that aresupposed to deliver services and protections to<strong>the</strong> poor suffer from malfeasance, underper<strong>for</strong>mance,or incompetence problems, and <strong>the</strong> poorare powerless to change this. Remedying thissituation requires re<strong>for</strong>m along two related dimensions:• The first dimension is public administration:How can we design bureaucracies that per<strong>for</strong>m<strong>the</strong>ir assigned functions with integrity, ef<strong>for</strong>t,and responsiveness to <strong>the</strong>ir clients? How canwe structure service processes, bureaucraticgrievance and dispute resolution proceduresthat are fair, efficient and user-focused?• The second dimension of bureaucratic justicere<strong>for</strong>m involves administrative law: What setof legal rules and procedures will empower <strong>the</strong>bureaucracy to achieve its goals while simultaneouslyconstraining potential abuses of power?What is <strong>the</strong> proper degree of judicial andpolitical oversight of government agencies?Public Administration Re<strong>for</strong>mTo improve access to bureaucratic justice throughre<strong>for</strong>m of public administration, re<strong>for</strong>mers shouldw<strong>ork</strong> to streng<strong>the</strong>n external monitoring and toimplement structural re<strong>for</strong>ms that will improvebureaucratic incentives and capabilities. Theright mix of re<strong>for</strong>m strategies will vary dependingon <strong>the</strong> political and institutional circumstances indifferent countries, and will also have to take intoaccount <strong>the</strong> specific social and cultural context.None<strong>the</strong>less, experience in a variety of countriessuggests that <strong>the</strong>re are some general lessons tobe drawn about <strong>the</strong> types of public administrationre<strong>for</strong>m that may be appropriate.External MonitoringEffective and responsive public administrationoften requires monitoring by entities outside <strong>the</strong>bureaucracy, including <strong>the</strong> intended recipientsof bureaucratic services, <strong>the</strong> general public, ando<strong>the</strong>r government agencies.One institutional re<strong>for</strong>m that many countries haveimplemented to improve monitoring is <strong>the</strong> establishmentof an independent ombudsman’s officeto respond to complaints and investigate allegationsof malfeasance. In Peru, <strong>for</strong> example, <strong>the</strong>ombudsman was able to resolve a dispute involvingallegations that an agency had overchargedconsumers <strong>for</strong> electricity and telephone services:After <strong>the</strong> ombudsman investigated, issued areport, and credibly threatened litigation, <strong>the</strong>agency took action to address <strong>the</strong> consumer complaints.The effectiveness of an ombudsman may,as this case illustrates, depend on backgroundinstitutions such as an effective court system thatgive o<strong>the</strong>r agencies an incentive to take <strong>the</strong>ombudsman’s recommendations seriously.The effectiveness of ombudsman offices mayalso depend on <strong>the</strong>ir resources. The Philippines,<strong>for</strong> example, has an ombudsman’s office that isconstitutionally very powerful, but chronic underfundinghas rendered it less effective in practice.Similarly, although <strong>the</strong> Pakistani ombudsman hassecured relief <strong>for</strong> some victims of maladministrationand has been hailed as one of <strong>the</strong> most successfulinstruments of <strong>the</strong> Pakistani governmentin serving <strong>the</strong> people, <strong>the</strong> number of complaintslodged has increased dramatically making <strong>the</strong> officegreatly overburdened. It has also been unableto address systematic bureaucratic failures thatgo beyond <strong>the</strong> resolution of individual disputes49


(ADB 2001b). These and o<strong>the</strong>r examples suggestthat while an ombudsman or and similar institutionaldevice may be helpful, it is not a panacea.O<strong>the</strong>r legal and institutional re<strong>for</strong>ms may improveaccess to bureaucratic justice by aiding<strong>the</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>ts of private individuals and organisationsto monitor <strong>the</strong> bureaucracy. Educating poorcommunities about <strong>the</strong>ir rights and means ofredress vis-à-vis <strong>the</strong> bureaucracy is an importantfirst step in ensuring bureaucratic accountability.Providing legal or quasi-legal assistance is ano<strong>the</strong>r.Both of <strong>the</strong>se issues are versions of <strong>the</strong> moregeneral issue of how to provide access to legalin<strong>for</strong>mation and legal services, discussed earlierin this chapter. However, particularly in caseswhere legal service providers support <strong>the</strong> publicagainst state behaviour, attention must be paid toinstitutional arrangements which protect <strong>the</strong> independenceof justice services providers, becausesuch services will inevitably be more threateningto <strong>the</strong> state than, say, health or education.Government agencies can and should take additionalsteps to facilitate monitoring of bureaucraticper<strong>for</strong>mance. For example, bureaucraciesshould employ an accessible case tracking system,which individuals and organisations canuse to monitor <strong>the</strong> progress of disputes through<strong>the</strong> bureaucratic system. USAID helped developa case tracking system in Bosnia-Herzegovinathat allows civil society organisations to monitorcases at various stages in <strong>the</strong> administrativeprocess and to draw <strong>the</strong> attention of responsibleauthorities to cases that have been ignored orseem to be languishing in <strong>the</strong> system without aresolution (USAID 2006). Ano<strong>the</strong>r approach thatcan contribute to increased public accountabilityis <strong>the</strong> introduction of citizen charters, which arepreferably developed in collaboration with <strong>the</strong>community. Citizen’s charters should containclear standards <strong>for</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance that are fit to bemeasured and benchmarked by <strong>the</strong> bureaucracy,independent agencies and <strong>the</strong> community itself.In this way <strong>the</strong> public has a yardstick <strong>for</strong> assessingpublic service delivery. An illustrative bottomup example of <strong>the</strong> citizenry measuring publicper<strong>for</strong>mance are <strong>the</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>ts of citizens’ groups inBangalore, India — <strong>the</strong>se groups conducted consumersurveys regarding <strong>the</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance of localgovernment agencies and published <strong>the</strong> resultsin order to create pressure <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m. This ‘namingand shaming’ approach spread to o<strong>the</strong>r statesin India as well (Narayan 2002). Where feasible,modern in<strong>for</strong>mation technology (e.g. Internet, cellphones, etc.) could be used to disseminate in<strong>for</strong>mationon bureaucratic per<strong>for</strong>mance more broadly,which would facilitate external monitoring.Structural Re<strong>for</strong>msAs useful as it may be to improve external monitoringmechanisms, significant progress towardimproving access to bureaucratic justice may requiremore systematic re<strong>for</strong>ms of <strong>the</strong> bureaucraticinstitutions <strong>the</strong>mselves. A starting point is <strong>the</strong>improvement of each agency’s internal adjudicativeprocedures, monitoring mechanisms, appealsprocesses, and grievance procedures. The administrativedispute resolution system and <strong>the</strong> publicinterventions aimed at facilitating <strong>the</strong> resolutionof disputes between private parties do not alwaysreceive as much attention from governments and<strong>the</strong> donor community as <strong>the</strong> judicial system, butmore people — and a larger proportion of poorpeople — are more likely to come into contactwith <strong>the</strong> bureaucratic system than <strong>the</strong> court system.(This would certainly be true of non-criminalmatters.) Government bureaucracies responsible<strong>for</strong> delivering essential services and <strong>for</strong> interventionsin relationships between citizens shouldhave a well-functioning system <strong>for</strong> providingen<strong>for</strong>cement and mediation services, addressingcomplaints, resolving disputes, and providing50


edress. These systems should be cost-efficient,transparent, user-friendly and swift.Asecond strategy <strong>for</strong> making public bureaucraciesmore responsive to <strong>the</strong> needs of poorcommunities is increasing <strong>the</strong> participation ofpoor communities, or <strong>the</strong> public generally, in bureaucraticdecision making. Participatory methodssuch as interest-based dialogs, consensusbuilding, and public collaboration aim to activelyengage people in decision-making processes thatconcern <strong>the</strong>ir lives (Vidoga, 2002). The possibilitiesto have input, to voice concerns, to makerecommendations and to co-produce outcomesare likely to improve <strong>the</strong> quality of public decisions.Participation fur<strong>the</strong>r increases <strong>the</strong> public’sunderstanding and acceptance of decisions, andadvances a sound partnership between <strong>the</strong> bureaucracyand <strong>the</strong> citizenry. An interesting exampleof participatory regulatory decision making is<strong>the</strong> system of municipal water regulation in PortoAlegre, Brazil. The municipality wholly owns <strong>the</strong>Porto Alegre Municipal Department of Water andSewage, but it is a separate legal entity with financialand operational autonomy. The mayor appoints<strong>the</strong> Department’s general director, but itsmanagement board includes representatives froma wide range of civil society organisations. PortoAlegre also uses a participatory budgeting processin which citizens register <strong>the</strong>ir vote on budgetpriorities after hearing presentations from <strong>the</strong>directors of different service departments. Overall,this arrangement appears to have succeededin creating incentives <strong>for</strong> high-quality service delivery(UNDP 2006).O<strong>the</strong>r countries have also experimented with participatoryregulatory decision-making. Vietnam,<strong>for</strong> example, recently established a legal framew<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong> consultative relations between local-leveladministrators and <strong>the</strong> people <strong>the</strong>y serve. Thisframew<strong>ork</strong> allows citizens to provide input andoversight in selected areas of local planning anddecision-making (ADB 2001c).Direct public participation in regulatory policymakingdoes have its drawbacks, however. Bureaucraciesdesiring to introduce participation shouldnot underestimate <strong>the</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>ts it will possibly take.Issues that need attention are, among o<strong>the</strong>rs, <strong>the</strong>design of <strong>the</strong> procedure <strong>for</strong> participation, <strong>the</strong> roleand authority citizens will have, and decisionsabout representation. For example, expectations onboth sides should be made clear from <strong>the</strong> beginningon. Decision-making processes may need tobe adjusted to <strong>the</strong> abilities of <strong>the</strong> non-professionalparticipants, who may be illiterate, inexperienced,or perhaps distrustful. The provision of supportivefacilities could be necessary, or <strong>the</strong> involvement ofneutrals and experts who can help to process in<strong>for</strong>mation,assess options and facilitate negotiations.And even so, not all issues might be equally suited<strong>for</strong> participatory decision-making. Sometimes, anagency needs to be able to credibly commit not tochange its policy in response to short-term publicpressure. It might be difficult, <strong>for</strong> example, to encouragelong-term investment in telecommunicationsinfrastructure if investors know that rates willbe set in participatory fashion by consumers: evenif consumers initially want to encourage investmentby promising a high rate of return, it may bedifficult <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>m to make that promise credible ifinvestors know that future rates will be set by anagency that is dominated by consumer interests(Levy and Spiller 1996, Henisz and Zelner 2001).A third strategy <strong>for</strong> improving access to bureaucraticjustice would emphasise re<strong>for</strong>ms that institutionalisestandards of good governance andpromote public services morale. By giving bureaucraticmanagers sufficient means to offer <strong>the</strong>irsubordinates incentives <strong>for</strong> good per<strong>for</strong>mance, todiscipline bad per<strong>for</strong>mance, and to reorganise outdatedpractices, bureaucratic organisations could51


e restructured in a way that reduces inefficiencyand waste and avoids inertia. This strategy may bepolitically sensitive, however. Civil service unionsare very powerful in many developing countries,and <strong>for</strong> decades <strong>the</strong>y and <strong>the</strong>ir members haveenjoyed almost complete tenure and salary protections,little oversight, and few serious demands. Itmay <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e be risky <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> government to takeon <strong>the</strong> civil service unions by proposing re<strong>for</strong>msthat would threaten <strong>the</strong> power or livelihoods of<strong>the</strong>se unions and <strong>the</strong>ir members. There<strong>for</strong>e, measuresenhancing bureaucratic justice and servicequality need to take into account <strong>the</strong> interestsof both <strong>the</strong> civil servants and <strong>the</strong>ir representingorganisations. Reorganisations might be moreacceptable if <strong>the</strong>y are build on trust ra<strong>the</strong>r thandisapproval, motivate good practices ra<strong>the</strong>r thanpunish incompetence, stimulate learning fromfeedback ra<strong>the</strong>r than reprimand underper<strong>for</strong>mance,and provide safeguards <strong>for</strong> justified concernsregarding job security, wage guarantees andstatus. Approaching this delicate issue <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>erequires skilful politicians to enter into a consensus-buildingprocess with stakeholders and puttoge<strong>the</strong>r ‘package deals’ in which <strong>the</strong> existing civilservice establishment is given benefits in exchange<strong>for</strong> accepting re<strong>for</strong>ms that promote greaterbureaucratic productivity and efficiency. As analternative or complementary strategy, re<strong>for</strong>merscould try to build a countervailing coalition thatwould push <strong>for</strong> bureaucratic re<strong>for</strong>m.A fourth type of strategy might promote decentralisation,bureaucratic redundancy, or somedegree of privatisation in service delivery, at least<strong>for</strong> certain types of service. The advantages ofdecentralisation are that it brings bureaucracy‘closer to <strong>the</strong> people’, may increase accountabilityand responsiveness to local needs, and maypromote healthy competition between regions iflocal governments have input into bureaucraticgovernance within <strong>the</strong>ir jurisdictions (Girishankaret al. 2002). Decentralization, however, mayincrease risks of corruption if it weakens centralizedoversight and depends on local individualsto make impartial decisions on matters affecting<strong>the</strong>ir family, friends, and enemies (UNDP 2006).Decentralization may also reduce competence ifpowerful central bureaucracies are more likely toattract talented individuals.Bureaucratic redundancy — that is, having two ormore separate agencies or office provide <strong>the</strong> sameservice to <strong>the</strong> same target population — has threemain advantages. First, it reduces <strong>the</strong> likelihoodof incompetence or corruption by giving consumerswith a choice of provider (Shleifer and Vishny1993). Second, if bureaucrats are rewarded atleast partially on <strong>the</strong> basis of demand <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>irservices, redundancy may lead to healthy competitionbetween providers. Third, redundancymay facilitate experimentation and innovation.Bureaucratic redundancy also has costs, however.The first and most obvious is <strong>the</strong> extra budgetarycost of staffing two or more offices to provide essentially<strong>the</strong> same service. The second concernis that <strong>the</strong> existence of multiple providers mayblur lines of accountability and, if incentives areimproperly aligned, may encourage bureaucrats to‘let <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r guy do <strong>the</strong> hard w<strong>ork</strong>’ (Ting 2003).Privatisation of service delivery functions holds<strong>the</strong> promise of more efficient service delivery.Consumer choice, value <strong>for</strong> money, proximity to<strong>the</strong> client and hands-on mentality are some appealingelements of this basic change towardsgovernance (Rhodes, 1997). The remix of bureaucraciesand markets containing <strong>the</strong> use ofbusiness principles and incentive structures isbelieved to motivate both <strong>the</strong> publicly and privatelyorganised service providers to adjust <strong>the</strong>service delivery to <strong>the</strong> specific customers’ needs,resulting in an increase in effectiveness, respon-52


siveness and transparency (Lane, 2000). However,privatisation also risks undermining publicaccountability and creating more opportunities <strong>for</strong>corruption. Some high-profile scandals have doneserious damage to <strong>the</strong> image of privatisation as are<strong>for</strong>m strategy. While <strong>the</strong>se cautionary tales illustrate<strong>the</strong> dangers of ill conceived or badly managedprivatisation ef<strong>for</strong>ts, <strong>the</strong>y should not obscure<strong>the</strong> fact that some privatisation schemes cansubstantially increase <strong>the</strong> access of poor communitiesto vital government services. For example,water provision in Chile is heavily privatised, butsubject to a strong regulatory system and coupledwith a subsidy programme to address equity concerns.The scheme is widely viewed as effectivein providing clean water to poor communitiesefficiently and equitably (UNDP 2006).Administrative <strong>Law</strong> Re<strong>for</strong>mIn addition to general public administrationre<strong>for</strong>ms, <strong>the</strong>re are a number of strategies <strong>for</strong>improving access to bureaucratic justice thatemphasise a more direct role <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> legal andjudicial system. Administrative law may affectbureaucratic per<strong>for</strong>mance in two distinct ways.First, legal rules en<strong>for</strong>ced by courts may facilitateor en<strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> public administration re<strong>for</strong>mstrategies discussed above. Second, courts andlitigants may take a more active role in overseeing<strong>the</strong> activities of <strong>the</strong> public bureaucracy. While administrativelitigation is only a small componentof a much larger set of governance institutions,and poor people are unlikely ever to be involveddirectly in a lawsuit against a bureaucratic agency,administrative law and litigation may none<strong>the</strong>lesshave an important role to play in expandingaccess to bureaucratic justice <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor. Thus,in this area of administrative law re<strong>for</strong>m, <strong>the</strong> issuesof access to bureaucratic justice and accessto legal justice overlap.Legal Mechanisms to Facilitate Participation andMonitoringThree major types of administrative law re<strong>for</strong>mmay enhance <strong>the</strong> efficacy of external monitoringmechanisms: freedom of in<strong>for</strong>mation (FOI) laws,‘impact statement’ requirements, and whistleblowerprotections.FOI laws are meant to increase <strong>the</strong> transparencyby giving citizens entitlement to in<strong>for</strong>mationabout bureaucratic rules, decisions, and practices.Traditionally, many governments resistedFOI legislation on grounds of privacy or secrecy,and certain private interests may oppose FOI legislationif <strong>the</strong>se interests benefit from <strong>the</strong> abilityto manipulate a relatively opaque administrativeprocess <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir own benefit. Despite this, recognitionof <strong>the</strong> benefits of FOI legislation seems tobe on <strong>the</strong> rise: 65 countries currently have some<strong>for</strong>m of FOI legislation, with most of those lawsenacted since 1990 (Kocaoglu and Figari 2006).FOI laws do have some important costs. Firstly,<strong>the</strong> traditional objections based on privacy or secrecyconcerns may have merit in some contexts.There<strong>for</strong>e, certain exemptions to FOI laws relatedto issues like national security, ongoing courtproceedings, and personal or commercial privacymay be appropriate, though <strong>the</strong>se exemptionsshould be narrowly drafted and construed. Secondly,in poor countries with weak bureaucraticcapacity, compliance with FOI requirements andresponding to FOI requests can be extremelycostly, and could end up paralysing <strong>the</strong> bureaucracy(Russell-Einhorn et al. 2002). This suggeststhat re<strong>for</strong>mers should be careful not to simply liftFOI laws ‘off <strong>the</strong> shelf’ from wealthy countries;ra<strong>the</strong>r, FOI laws must be carefully tailored to <strong>the</strong>needs and capacities of particular countries.Impact statement’ legislation requires a governmentagency to provide a public report on <strong>the</strong>53


impact of a proposed action on some importantpublic value be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong> agency takes action.The most common legislation of this type is <strong>the</strong>‘environmental impact statement’ requirementpioneered by <strong>the</strong> U.S. National EnvironmentalPolicy Act of 1970 and adopted by numerouso<strong>the</strong>r countries and some international organisations.Though <strong>the</strong> specifics of <strong>the</strong>se laws vary,<strong>the</strong>y all require that agencies prepare a report on<strong>the</strong> impact of major proposed actions on environmentalquality. O<strong>the</strong>r types of impact statementrequirements have also been proposed, and afew have been implemented, though <strong>the</strong> environmentalimpact statement is still by far <strong>the</strong> mostcommon version of this strategy. One approachthat might be worth considering is <strong>the</strong> use of a‘poverty impact statement’ that would requireagencies, after consulting <strong>the</strong> poor community, toproduce a report on how <strong>the</strong>ir initiatives are likelyto affect <strong>the</strong> poor. The main advantages of impactstatement laws are, first, that <strong>the</strong>y increasepublic accountability and <strong>the</strong> efficacy of externaloversight by disclosing potential adverse effectsof agency action, and, second, that <strong>the</strong>y mayalter <strong>the</strong> agency’s own internal decision-makingprocess by drawing attention to issues that mighto<strong>the</strong>rwise be ignored or neglected. However, impactstatement requirements, like FOI legislation,can be burdensome, especially <strong>for</strong> under-fundedor low-capacity agencies. Saddling bureaucracieswith too many impact statement requirementsmay induce ‘paralysis by analysis’. The appropriatebalance between <strong>the</strong>se competing interestscannot be resolved in abstract or general terms.Whistleblower protection statutes are a third<strong>for</strong>m of administrative law re<strong>for</strong>m that seeks toimprove transparency and political accountability.Without credible protections, individuals withina bureaucratic organisation who learn about corruptionor o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>ms of malfeasance will be reluctantto come <strong>for</strong>ward because <strong>the</strong>y fear retaliation.Effective whistleblower protection statutestypically enable individuals to make complaintsanonymously or confidentially, imposing seriouscivil and criminal penalties on those who retaliateagainst whistleblowers, and (sometimes) givingpotential whistleblowers a financial incentive tocome <strong>for</strong>ward ei<strong>the</strong>r by offering <strong>the</strong>m a set ‘bounty’<strong>for</strong> useful in<strong>for</strong>mation or by offering <strong>the</strong>m apercentage of any money <strong>the</strong> government recoversfrom wrongdoers as a result of <strong>the</strong> whistleblower’sreport. Whistleblower protection statutes may notbe effective in redressing endemic or high-levelcorruption, especially when <strong>the</strong> en<strong>for</strong>cement of<strong>the</strong> laws is unreliable, but <strong>the</strong>se statutes maynone<strong>the</strong>less be effective and important elementsof a broader anti-corruption strategy.Judicial Review of Administrative DecisionsFOI legislation, impact statement laws, andwhistleblower protection statutes are all legalmechanisms through which courts en<strong>for</strong>ce rulesthat enable o<strong>the</strong>r actors — NGOs, politicians, and<strong>the</strong> media — to monitor bureaucratic per<strong>for</strong>mancemore effectively. Thus, increasing <strong>the</strong> abilityof individuals and groups to make sure <strong>the</strong>se lawsare en<strong>for</strong>ced may improve poor people’s access tobureaucratic justice.Litigation and judicial institutions may also play amore direct role in ensuring bureaucratic accountability.Such litigation can take two main <strong>for</strong>ms.First, some litigants pursue what might be termed‘oversight’ litigation. Individuals who believe thata government agency has taken, or is about totake, some illegal action that adversely affects<strong>the</strong>ir interests may file a legal challenge. The judiciary<strong>the</strong>n assumes <strong>the</strong> role of public monitor,ensuring that <strong>the</strong> agency has acted lawfully.The second <strong>for</strong>m of litigation is so-called ‘publicinterest litigation’ (PIL). Citizen groups typically54


ing PIL suits to effect broader legal change orinstitutional re<strong>for</strong>m. PIL has played a significantrole in <strong>the</strong> strategy of social re<strong>for</strong>m movementsin South Asia and South Africa in particular, andit is increasingly common in o<strong>the</strong>r parts of <strong>the</strong>world as well (NCLEP India 2007, Dembrowski2000, Gloppen 2005, Hershkoff and McCrutcheon2000). The distinction between oversightlitigation and PIL is more a matter of degree thana difference in kind. Oversight litigation moreclosely resembles a traditional lawsuit alleging aprivate injury to a legally protected interest, whilePIL seeks to involve <strong>the</strong> judiciary in a more overtlylaw-making or re<strong>for</strong>mist role, but in practicemany oversight suits seek institutional changes,and much PIL is directed toward <strong>the</strong> redress ofwidely-shared private grievances against bureaucraticinstitutions.Litigation is not <strong>the</strong> most desirable <strong>for</strong>m of improvingadministrative accountability and bureaucraticjustice. In <strong>the</strong> first place, any strategy thatrelies on litigation and judicial review is likelyto be expensive and time-consuming. ‘Retail’administrative lawsuits may also put an enormousburden on <strong>the</strong> court system. For example,in many Latin American countries citizens whobelieve <strong>the</strong>y have been wrongly denied a governmentbenefit can file an amparo claim directlyin <strong>the</strong> civil courts, <strong>the</strong>reby circumventing <strong>the</strong> administrativereview process. These amparo claimsclog <strong>the</strong> courts, and because <strong>the</strong>y are focusedonly on <strong>the</strong> individual claim <strong>the</strong>y tend not to address<strong>the</strong> root cause of bureaucratic failure.Secondly, courts may lack <strong>the</strong> expertise neededto understand <strong>the</strong> complex, technical issues thatoften arise in administrative law or institutionalre<strong>for</strong>m cases. Judges, however, may overestimate<strong>the</strong>ir own competence in such matters. Somecountries have attempted to address this problemby establishing specialised administrative courts,but even in <strong>the</strong>se cases judges are at a comparativedisadvantage compared to o<strong>the</strong>r institutionswhen considering issues of bureaucratic institutionaldesign.Finally, some observers have raised <strong>the</strong> concernthat well-intentioned re<strong>for</strong>mers, especially thosewith elite legal backgrounds, may be seducedby <strong>the</strong> appeal of litigation as a vehicle of socialchange and pursue this strategy at <strong>the</strong> expenseof more valuable — but less visible and exciting— political organisation, lobbying, and education.The three concerns cited are all valid, and litigationshould generally not be <strong>the</strong> first line ofdefence (or offence) in dealing with an abusive,unaccountable, or underper<strong>for</strong>ming bureaucracy.Never<strong>the</strong>less, having available litigation as aweapon of last resort may be vital in making <strong>the</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r mechanisms of bureaucratic justice functioneffectively. The principles that should applyto both to administrative oversight litigationand to PIL are <strong>the</strong> same as those discussed in<strong>the</strong> context of access to legal justice generally:re<strong>for</strong>mers should w<strong>ork</strong> to eliminate failures in<strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong> legal services and litigation, andestablish institutions that allocate scarce judicialresources to <strong>the</strong> cases where judicial interventionis most necessary and appropriate. Thus, desirableapproaches may include broadening rulesof standing, adopting one-way fee-shifting rules,facilitating representative or collective lawsuits,and targeting scarce legal aid resources at casesthat affect large numbers of people, while at <strong>the</strong>same time re<strong>for</strong>mer should provide more optionsand resources <strong>for</strong> non-judicial relief of administrativedisputes, and should require exhaustionof administrative remedies as a precondition <strong>for</strong>judicial review.55


5. Conclusions andRecommendationsIn order to escape <strong>the</strong> poverty trap, poor peopleneed a legal system that enables <strong>the</strong>m to realise<strong>the</strong> full value of <strong>the</strong>ir physical and humancapital. The three substantive cornerstones of<strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agenda are property law,labour law, and law <strong>for</strong> small business. Re<strong>for</strong>mof <strong>the</strong> substantive law, however necessary, wouldnot be sufficient to achieve true legal empowerment.For <strong>the</strong> legal system to play a role inempowering <strong>the</strong> poor to lift <strong>the</strong>mselves out ofpoverty, <strong>the</strong>y need more than laws conferring <strong>the</strong>appropriate mix of rights, powers, privileges, andimmunities; <strong>the</strong>y also need a legal and judicialsystem that can make <strong>the</strong>se legal entitlementspractical and meaningful. Empowering <strong>the</strong> poorand disadvantaged to seek remedies <strong>for</strong> injusticerequires ef<strong>for</strong>ts to develop and/or streng<strong>the</strong>n linkagesbetween <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>mal structures andto counter biases inherent in both systems. Ourw<strong>ork</strong>ing group has examined <strong>the</strong> issues involvedand has developed guidelines to provide ways ofimproving access to justice.Summarising our main conclusions, we stressthat access to justice requires granting allpeople an individual identity (see Section 2 ofthis chapter), and that realising this goal requires:• Addressing <strong>the</strong> lack of bureaucratic capacityin states’ identity registration systems byeliminating user fees, supporting outreach,w<strong>ork</strong>ing through non-governmental organisations,and bundling registration services witho<strong>the</strong>r social services or traditional practicesand creating one stop shops.• Counteracting politically-motivated legal exclusionby a combination of facilitation ofpolitical dialogue, legislative re<strong>for</strong>m, internationalattention, engaging national humanrights machineries, stakeholder consultations,and community involvement.• Creating incentives to register one’s legal identitywith <strong>the</strong> state by providing in<strong>for</strong>mation,w<strong>ork</strong>ing through trustworthy local intermediaries,and minimising <strong>the</strong> adverse consequencesof <strong>for</strong>mal registration.In Section 3 of this chapter, we identified fourstrategies to improve access to justice, taking <strong>the</strong>justifiable problems of <strong>the</strong> poor as starting points.They build on <strong>the</strong> options poor people have availableto address <strong>the</strong>se problems and to en<strong>for</strong>ce<strong>the</strong>ir rights: spontaneous ordering mechanisms,in<strong>for</strong>mal, faith-based and customary justice, aswell as <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal legal system. The common aimof <strong>the</strong>se strategies is to lower costs that may beinvolved and increase justness and fairness of <strong>the</strong>outcomes poor people may obtain. These strategieshave proven <strong>the</strong>ir value in practice, or seemparticularly promising in <strong>the</strong> light of a <strong>the</strong>oreticalframew<strong>ork</strong> that emphasises reduction of transactioncosts and remedying market failure:• Empowering <strong>the</strong> poor through improved disseminationof legal in<strong>for</strong>mation and <strong>for</strong>mationof peer groups (self-help strategies). This canbe done by streng<strong>the</strong>ning in<strong>for</strong>mation-sharingnetw<strong>ork</strong>s across consumer groups and organisations,by using in<strong>for</strong>mation technology, non<strong>for</strong>mallegal education and media campaigns,tailored to <strong>the</strong> target population and <strong>the</strong>irproblems.• Broadening <strong>the</strong> scope of legal services <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>poor, in several directions: an orientation towardsempowerment, coaching and learning;lower cost delivery-models (through paralegals,or o<strong>the</strong>rwise); bundling with o<strong>the</strong>r services(health care, banking, insurance) and intro-56


ducing <strong>the</strong> concept of one stop shop; use of<strong>the</strong> methods and skills of alternative disputeresolution, mediation and arbitration; and legalaid services that are capable of assistancewith <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal system as well as <strong>the</strong> statesystem. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong> legal servicesshould gradually be liberalised by reducingregulatory entry barriers (such as ‘unauthorisedpractice of law’ restriction) <strong>for</strong> serviceproviders, including non-lawyers, who are interestedin offering legal services to <strong>the</strong> poor.Scarce legal aid resources should be targetedto cases where <strong>the</strong> legal claim produces publicgoods (such as general deterrence or legalre<strong>for</strong>m) and to situations with very high stakes<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> individual (such as criminal defence).• Reducing aggregate legal transaction costs byadopting a combination of legal simplificationand standardisation re<strong>for</strong>ms, expanded opportunities<strong>for</strong> representative or aggregate legalclaims, and improving <strong>the</strong> climate <strong>for</strong> fair settlementsin <strong>the</strong> shadow of law, by ensuring acredible threat of a neutral intervention.• Combining <strong>for</strong>mal or tacit recognition of <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal justice system with education andawareness campaigns that promote evolutionof <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal state system, targeted constraintson <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal system (in particularlimits on practices that perpetuate <strong>the</strong> subordinationof women), and appropriately structuring<strong>the</strong> relationship between state and nonstatesystems so that <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal system canprovide an efficient means of resolving privatedisputes, but people are able to use <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>malsystem when crime and fundamental publicvalues are implicated.and obtain necessary services, access to justicere<strong>for</strong>m may require not only improving access toadjudicative justice, but also improving access tobureaucratic justice (discussed in Section 4). Addressing<strong>the</strong> failures of <strong>the</strong> bureaucratic systemmay entail:• Public administration re<strong>for</strong>ms, includingre<strong>for</strong>ms that improve external monitoringand also structural re<strong>for</strong>ms (such as improvingbureaucratic adjudication and grievanceprocedures, expanding public participationin administrative decision-making, pursuingcivil service re<strong>for</strong>m to expand opportunities <strong>for</strong>per<strong>for</strong>mance incentives in government administration,and increasing decentralisation andredundancy in bureaucratic service provisionto improve efficiency and combat corruption.• Administrative law re<strong>for</strong>ms, including appropriately-tailoredexpansions of freedom ofin<strong>for</strong>mation laws, impact statement requirements,and whistleblower protections, as wellas appropriate but limited judicial review ofadministrative action.Because many poor people have to rely on accessto <strong>the</strong> (local) government hierarchy ra<strong>the</strong>r than<strong>the</strong> adjudicative system to resolve <strong>the</strong>ir disputes57


Chapter 1 Endnotes1 Excellent recent reports prepared by <strong>the</strong> Asian Development Bank(ADB) (2004, 2005, 2007), UNICEF (2002, 2005), and <strong>the</strong> Inter-AmericanDevelopment Bank (IADB) (2006) <strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> basis of much of <strong>the</strong>material in this section. These organisations have taken an importantleadership role by bringing this problem to <strong>the</strong> attention of <strong>the</strong> internationalcommunity - ga<strong>the</strong>ring vital in<strong>for</strong>mation on <strong>the</strong> nature andscope of <strong>the</strong> problem and developing possible strategies <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m.2 For example, <strong>the</strong> International Covenant on Civil and PoliticalRights, Arts. 16 and 24; International Covenant on Economic, Social,and Cultural Rights, Arts. 6 and 13; Convention on <strong>the</strong> Rights of <strong>the</strong>Child, Arts. 7—8; International Convention on <strong>the</strong> Protection of <strong>the</strong>Rights of All Migrant W<strong>ork</strong>ers, Art. 9; Convention on <strong>the</strong> Elimination ofAll Forms of Discrimination Against Women, Arts. 7—9; American Conventionon Human Rights, Art. 20; European Convention on Nationality,Art. 6; African Charter on <strong>the</strong> Rights and Welfare of <strong>the</strong> Child, Arts. 6and 11.3 Sources discussing <strong>the</strong>se and o<strong>the</strong>r groups include Lynch and Ali(2006), Lynch (2005), Amnesty International (2005), Sokoloff (2006),Refugees International (2006), Kalvaitis (1998), and Adam (2006).4 Describing this barrier as a ‘transaction cost’ is not meant totrivialise <strong>the</strong> feelings of cultural and social exclusion this linguisticbarrier may also engender. This phenomenon may create a type ofpsychological cost to using <strong>the</strong> legal system that is as signifi cant, inpractical terms, as <strong>the</strong> economic cost.5 It is worth noting, however, that <strong>the</strong> issue of linguistic barriers toaccess, like <strong>the</strong> issue of legal identity discussed earlier, may implicateserious political confl icts. Sometimes linguistic barriers to access arisebecause of government policies designed specifi cally to disadvantageparticular ethnic groups, or to advantage <strong>the</strong> wealthy relative to <strong>the</strong>poor. Thus, even if <strong>the</strong> fi nancial costs of dealing with this particularobstacle may be relatively low, <strong>the</strong> political costs may be greater.6 Much of this discussion is based on an excellent recent reportprepared by Ewa Wojkowska (2006) of <strong>the</strong> UNDP’s Oslo GovernanceCentre.Chapter 1 BibliographyAdam, A.H. 2006. The Nubians and Statelessness: History in Defi ningModern Lives, available at http://www.justiceinitiative.org/statelessness_meeting.Afroz, T. 2006. ‘Access to <strong>Law</strong>: The Bangladesh Perspective.’ availableat http://www.adb.org/Documents/Books/Streng<strong>the</strong>ning-Criminal-Justice-system/chap04.Anderson, M.2003. Access to Justice and Legal Process: <strong>Making</strong> LegalInstitutions Responsive to Poor People in LDCs (IDS W<strong>ork</strong>ingPaper 178, Feb. 2003).Ardaya, G. and G. Sierra.2002. Toward an Inclusive Elections Process:Final Report of Pro-Citizens’ Participation Consortium.UKDepartment <strong>for</strong> International Development. La Paz, Bolivia.Amnesty International.2005. Myanmar: The Rohingya Minority: FundamentalRights Denied. available at: http://www.justiceinitiative.org/statelessness_meeting.Asian Development Bank (ADB). 2001a. <strong>Law</strong> and Policy Re<strong>for</strong>m at <strong>the</strong>Asian Development Bank 2000. vol. 2, available at http://www.asianlii.org/asia/o<strong>the</strong>r/ADBLPRes/2001/2.pdf._____. 2001b. Report and Recommendation of <strong>the</strong> President to <strong>the</strong>Board of Directors on Proposed and Technical AssistanceGrant to <strong>the</strong> Islamic Republic of Pakistan <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Access toJustice Programme, available at http://www.adb.org/Documents/RRPS/PAK/rrp_32023.pdf._____. (ADB) 2001c. Legal Empowerment: Advancing Good Governanceand Poverty Reduction, 2000, available at http://www.adb.org/Documents/O<strong>the</strong>rs/<strong>Law</strong>_ADB/lpr_2001_Part_2.pdf._____. 2002. Technical Assistance Completion Report — Disseminating<strong>Law</strong>s and Streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong> Legal In<strong>for</strong>mation System,TA 3238-TAJ, available at http://www.adb.org/Documents/TACRs/TAJ/tacr_taj_3238.pdf._____. 2004., Technical Assistance <strong>for</strong> Establishing Legal Identity <strong>for</strong>Social Inclusion, R188-04 (Oct. 4, 2004)._____. 2005. Inception Report: Establishing Legal Identity <strong>for</strong> SocialInclusion, RETA No. 6188 Aug.10, 2005)._____. 2007. Legal Identity <strong>for</strong> Inclusive Development (CarolineVandanabeele and Christine V. Lao, eds.).Axworthy, L. 2007. Quoted in ‘Toward Consensus.’ Legal EmpowermentQuarterly. July 2007.p. 2.Barendrecht, M. and P. van Nispen, Micro-justice (International LegalAlliances), available at http://www.intall.org/documents/PaperMicrojustice0704.pdf.Barton, B. 2001. ‘Why Do We Regulate <strong>Law</strong>yers?: An EconomicAnalysis of <strong>the</strong> Justifi cations <strong>for</strong> Entry and ConductRegulation.’Arizona State <strong>Law</strong> Journal 33:429-490.Bloom, A.2006. ‘The Economics of Civil Justice: From Justice to GlobalPeace: A (Brief) Genealogy of <strong>the</strong> Class Action Crisis.’Loyolaof Los Angeles <strong>Law</strong> Review. 39:719.Bolton, P. and M. Dewatripont.2005. Contract Theory. Cambridge andLondon: MIT Press.Bueno de Mesquita, E. and M. Stephenson. 2007. ‘Regulatory QualityUnder Imperfect Oversight.’ American Political ScienceReview. 101(3):605-620.58


Buscaglia, E. and T. Ulen. 1997. ‘A Quantitative Assessment of <strong>the</strong>Effi ciency of <strong>the</strong> Judicial Sector in Latin America.’ InternationalReview of <strong>Law</strong> and Economics. 17:275.Cantrell, D. 2004. ‘Deborah L. Rhode’s Access to Justice: The Obligationof Legal Aid <strong>Law</strong>yers To Champion Practice by Nonlawyers.’Fordham <strong>Law</strong> Review. 73:883.Capper, D. 2003. ‘The Contingency Legal Aid Fund: A Third Way toFinance Personal Injury Litigation.’ Journal of <strong>Law</strong> andSociety. 30(1):66-83.Caro<strong>the</strong>rs, T. 2003: ‘Promoting <strong>the</strong> Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Abroad: The Problem ofKnowledge.’ Carnegie Endowment WOrking Paper No. 34.Washington, D.C. January 2003Centre <strong>for</strong> Applied Legal Studies.2002. Final Report on Gender, Citizenshipand Governance Project.Damazo, J. 2006. Registering a New Sense of Identity, available athttp://www.adb.org/media/Articles/2006/11077-Cambodialegal-identity/.Dembowski, H. 2000. Taking <strong>the</strong> State to Court: Public Interest Litigationand <strong>the</strong> Public Sphere in India.Domberger, S. and A. Sherr.1989. ‘The Impact of Competition on Pricingand Quality of Legal Services.’ International Review of <strong>Law</strong>and Economics. 9:41-56.Dun<strong>for</strong>d, C. 2002.’Building Better Lives: Sustainable Integration ofMicro-fi nance with Education in Child Survival, ReproductiveHealth, and HIV/AIDS Prevention <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poorest Entrepreneurs.’In: Daley-Harris, S. ed., Pathways Out of Poverty.Bloomfi eld, Conn: Kumarian Press, Inc.Faundez, J. 2006. ‘Should Justice Re<strong>for</strong>m Projects Take Non-State JusticeSystems Seriously? Perspectives from Latin America.’in The World Bank Legal Review: <strong>Law</strong>, Equity, and Development.Galanter, M. 1976., ‘Delivering Legality: Some Proposals <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Directionof Research.’ <strong>Law</strong> and Society Review. 11:225-246._____. M. 1974. ‘Why <strong>the</strong> ‘Haves’ Come Out Ahead: Speculations on<strong>the</strong> Limits of Legal Change.’<strong>Law</strong> and Society Review. 9:95-160.Gidi, A. 2003. ‘Class Actions in Brazil — A Model <strong>for</strong> Civil <strong>Law</strong>Countries.’American Journal of Comparative <strong>Law</strong>. 51:311-.Girishankar, N. et al. 2002. ‘Governance,’ in Klugman, J., ed., A Sourcebook<strong>for</strong> Poverty Reduction Strategies, available at http://poverty2.<strong>for</strong>umone.com/fi les/4105_cahp8.pdf.Gloppen, S. 2005.,Public Interest Litigation, Social Rights and SocialPolicy, available at http://siteresources.worldbank.org/IN-TRANETSOCI<strong>AL</strong>DEVELOPMENT/Resources/Gloppen.rev.3. pdf.Golub, S. 2000. ‘Beyond <strong>the</strong> Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Orthodoxy: The Legal EmpowermentAlternative.’ Carnegie Endowment W<strong>ork</strong>ing PaperNo. 41. Washington, D.C. October 2003._____. 2003. The Legal Empowerment Alternative, in T. Caro<strong>the</strong>rs ed.,Promoting <strong>the</strong> Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Abroad, In Search of Knowledge._____. 2004., Forging <strong>the</strong> Future: Engaging <strong>Law</strong> Students andYoung <strong>Law</strong>yers in Public Service, Human Rights, andPoverty Alleviation (Open Society Justice Initiative IssuesPaper), available at http://www.justiceinitiative.org/db/resource2?res_id=101449._____. ‘Combating Corruption in Non-judicial Justice Systems.’ inGlobal Corruption Report 2007. Transparency International(London: Pluto Press, 2007).Grajzl, P. and P. Murrell. 2006. ‘<strong>Law</strong>yers and Politicians: The Impactof Organised Legal Professions on Institutional Re<strong>for</strong>ms.’Constitutional Political Economy.17(4):251-276.Hammergren, L. 2007. Access to Justice: Legal Assistance, SpecialCourts, ADR, and Beyond.Hay, J., A. Shleifer and R. Vishny.1996. ‘Toward a Theory of Legal Re<strong>for</strong>m.’European Economic Review. 40:559-567.Henisz, W. and B. Zelner.2001. ‘The Institutional Environment <strong>for</strong>Telecommunications Investment.’ Journal of Economics andManagement Strategy 10(1):123-147.Hershkoff, H. and A. McCutcheon.2000. ‘Public Interest Litigation:An International Perspective,’ in Many Roads to Justice:The <strong>Law</strong>-Related W<strong>ork</strong> of Foundation Grantees Around <strong>the</strong>World. McClymont, M. and S. Golub, eds. New Y<strong>ork</strong>: FordFoundation.Hoffman, M., P. Rubin and J. Shepherd.2005. ‘An Empirical Studyof Public Defender Effectiveness: Self-Selection by <strong>the</strong>‘Marginally Indigent’.’ Ohio State Journal of Criminal <strong>Law</strong>3:223-255.Huber, J. and N. McCarty. 2004. ‘Bureaucratic Capacity, Delegation,and Political Re<strong>for</strong>m.’ American Political Science Review.98(3):481-494.Inter-American Development Bank (IADB).2006. Hidden in Plain Sight:Undocumented Citizens in Latin America. Ideas <strong>for</strong> Developmentin <strong>the</strong> Americas 1 (Jan.-Apr. 2006).Kalvaitis, R. 1998. ‘Citizenship and National Identity in <strong>the</strong> BalticStates.’ Boston University International <strong>Law</strong> Journal.16:231.Kennedy, A.2007. Rule of <strong>Law</strong> (LEP Commission Discussion Paper).Killian, M. 2003. ‘Alternatives to Public Provision: The Role of LegalExpenses Insurance in Broadening Access to Justice: TheGerman Experience.’ Journal of <strong>Law</strong> and Society. 30(1):31-48.Kocaoglu, N. and A. Figari. 2006. Using <strong>the</strong> Right to In<strong>for</strong>mation as anAnti-Corruption Tool. (Transparency International), availableat http://www.transparentnost.org.yu/aktivnosti/slobodan_pristup_inf/TI2006_europe_access_in<strong>for</strong>mation.pdf.Kritzer, H. 1997. ‘Rethinking Barriers to Legal Practice.’ Judicature81(3):100-103._____. 2004. Risks, Reputations, and Rewards: Contingency FeeLegal Practice in <strong>the</strong> United States.Laczo, M. 2003. ‘Deprived of an Individual Identity: Citizenship andWomen in Nepal.’Gender and Development. 11(3):76-82.Landes, W. and R. Posner. 1979. ‘Adjudication as a Private Good.’Journal of Legal Studies 8:235-284.Lane, Jan-Erik. 2000. New Public Management. New Y<strong>ork</strong>: Routledge.Levy, B. and P. Spiller. 1996. Regulations, Institutions, and Commitment:A Comparative Analysis of TelecommunicationsRegulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Lin, Zixin. 2006. Thailand: Faster Citizenship <strong>for</strong> Hilltribes Pushed,available at http://www.newsmekong.org/thailand_faster_citizenship_<strong>for</strong>_hilltribes_pushed.59


Lopez-de-Silanes, F. 2002. The Politics of Legal Re<strong>for</strong>m (U.N. Conferenceon Trade and Development. G-24 Discussion PaperSeries No. 17), available at http://www.unctad.org/en/docs/pogdsmdpbg24d17.en.pdf.Lynch, M. 2005. ‘Lives on Hold: The Human Cost of Statelessness.’Refugees International 23.Lynch, M. and P. Ali. 2006. Buried Alive: The Kurds in Syria, RefugeesInternational. Jan. 2006.MacCormack, D.N. and R. Summers eds. 1991. Interpreting Statutes: AComparative Study._____. 1997. Interpreting Precedent: A Comparative Study.Maru, V. 2006. ‘Between <strong>Law</strong> and Society: Paralegals and <strong>the</strong> Provisionof Justice Services in Sierra Leone and Worldwide.’YaleJournal of International <strong>Law</strong>. 31:427-476.McClymont, M. and S. Golub, eds . 2000. Many Roads to Justice: The<strong>Law</strong>-Related W<strong>ork</strong> of Ford Foundation: Grantees Around <strong>the</strong>World. Ford Foundation. 2000.McQuoid-Mason, D.2000. “The Delivery of Civil Legal Aid Servicesin South Africa.’ Fordham International <strong>Law</strong> Journal. 24:S111-S142.Menon, N.R.M. 2007..’Legal Education and Training in Bangladesh.’In:Streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong> CriminalJustice System . Asian DevelopmentBank.Messick, R. 1999. Judicial ‘Re<strong>for</strong>m and Economic Development: ASurvey of <strong>the</strong> Issues.’ The World Bank Research Observer.14(1):117-136.Michelson, E. 2007. ‘Climbing <strong>the</strong> Dispute Pagoda: Grievances andAppeals to <strong>the</strong> Offi cial Justice System in Rural China.’American Sociological Review. 72,2:459—485, 2007.Millennium Promise. 2007. ‘Millennium Villages: A Revolution Is Possible.’available at http://www.millenniumpromise.org/site/PageServer?pagename=mv_main.Murphy, K., A. Shleifer and R. Vishny.1991.’The Allocation of Talent:Implications <strong>for</strong> Growth.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics.106(2):503-530.Narayan, D. 2002.Empowerment and Poverty Reduction: A Sourcebook.________. 2005. Measuring Empowerment; Cross Disciplinary Perspectives,IBRD/World Bank.National Consultations on Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor (NCLEP)Ethiopia, Paper prepared on Access to Justice.2007._____. India, Paper prepared on Access to Justice. 2007._____. Indonesia, Paper prepared on Access to Justice.2007._____. Kenya, Paper prepared on Access to Justice.2007._____. Pakistan, Paper prepared on Access to Justice.2007._____. Philippines, Paper prepared on Access to Justice.2007._____. Tanzania, Paper prepared on Access to Justice. 2007._____. Uganda, Paper prepared on Access to Justice.2007.Open Society Institute . 2004. ‘Justice Initiatives: Legal Aid Re<strong>for</strong>mand Access to Justice.’ Feb. 2004, available at http://www.soros.org/resources/articles_publications/publications/justice_20040225/justice_initiatives_20040225_2.pdfPaldi, B. 2006. ‘A Step Towards Peace.’ ACE Electoral KnowledgeNetw<strong>ork</strong>, available at http://aceproject.org/today/featurearticles/a-step-towards-peace.Posner, R. 1998. Creating a Legal Framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> Economic Development.World Bank Research Observer 13:1-11.Refugees International, Stateless Biharis in Bangladesh: A HumanitarianNightmare, available at http://www.refugeesinternational.org/content/article/detail/4666/.Regan, F. 2003. ‘The Swedish Legal Services Policy Remix: The Shiftfrom Public Legal Aid to Private Legal Expense Insurance.’Journal of <strong>Law</strong> and Society. 30(1):49-65.Rhode, D. 2000. In <strong>the</strong> Interest of Justice: Re<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>the</strong> legal profession.New Y<strong>ork</strong>: Ox<strong>for</strong>d University Press._____. 2004. Access to Justice. New Y<strong>ork</strong>: Ox<strong>for</strong>d University Press._____. Rhodes, R.A.W. 1997. Understanding Governance; Policy Netw<strong>ork</strong>s,Governance,Refl exivity and Accountability. Buckingham, Philadelphia: Open UniversityPress.Russell-Einhorn, M. et al. 2002. ‘Streng<strong>the</strong>ning Access to In<strong>for</strong>mationand Public Participation inTransition Countries — Latviaas a Case Study in Administrative <strong>Law</strong> Re<strong>for</strong>m.’ Administrative<strong>Law</strong> Review. 54:459-.Schwartz, A., and L. Wilde.1979. ‘Intervening in Markets on <strong>the</strong> Basisof Imperfect In<strong>for</strong>mation: A Legal and Economic Analysis.’University of Pennsylvania <strong>Law</strong> Review. 127:630-.Shavell, S. 1995. ‘Alternative Dispute Resolution: An Economic Analysis.’Journal of Legal Studies. 24:1-28._____. 1997. ‘The Fundamental Divergence Between <strong>the</strong> Private and<strong>the</strong> Social Motive to Use <strong>the</strong> Legal System.’ Journal of LegalStudies. 26:575-612._____. 1982. ‘Suit, Settlement, and Trial: A Theoretical Analysis UnderAlternative Methods <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Allocation of Legal Costs.’Journal of Legal Studies. 11(1):55-81.Shleifer, A., and R. Vishny.1993. ‘Corruption.’ Quarterly Journal ofEconomics 108(3):599-617.Sokoloff, C. 2006. Denial of Citizenship: A Challenge to Human Security.Spaulding, N.2004. ‘The Luxury of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Law</strong>: The Codifi cation Movementand <strong>the</strong> Right to Counsel.’ Fordham <strong>Law</strong> Review 73:983-.Thomas, G. and A. Shrestha. 1998. Breaking New Ground: A Case Studyof Women’s Empowerment in Nepal, Women’s EmpowermentProgramme (USAID/Nepal)Ting, M.2003. ‘A Strategic Theory of Bureaucratic Redundancy.’ AmericanJournal of Political Science. 47(2):274-292.Tsikata, D. 2003. ‘Securing Women’s Interests Within Land TenureRe<strong>for</strong>ms: Recent Debates in Tanzania.’ Journal of AgrarianChange. 3:149-183.UNICEF. 2006. Birth Registration in Bangladesh, available at http://www.unicef.org/bangladesh/Birth_Registration_in_Bangladesh.pdf._____. 2005. The ‘Rights’ Start to Life: A Statistical Analysis of BirthRegistration, available at http://www.childinfo.org/areas/birthregistration/docs/Full%20text%20English.pdf.______. 2003. Birth Registration, available at http://www.unicef.org/southafrica/protection_761.html.______. 2002. ‘Birth Registration: Right from <strong>the</strong> Start.’ InnocentiDigest 9:1.60


United Nations Development Programme (UNDP). 2005. Programming<strong>for</strong> Justice: Access <strong>for</strong> All; A Human Rights-Based Approachto Access to Justice, available at http://regionalcenterbankok.undp.or.th/practices/governance/a2j/tools/index1.htm._____. 2006. U.N. Human Development Report 2006 — BeyondScarcity: Power, Poverty, and <strong>the</strong> Global Water Crisis._____. 2007. Human Security in Bangladesh: In Search of Justice andDignity._____. (UNDP Indonesia.) 2007 Justice For All? — An Assessment ofAccess to Justice in Five Provinces of Indonesia.United States Agency <strong>for</strong> International Development (USAID).2002.Achievements in Building and Maintaining <strong>the</strong> Rule of <strong>Law</strong>:MSI’s Studies in LAC, EandE, AFR, and ANE. OccasionalPaper Series by USAID. Nov. 2002, available at http://www.usaid.gov/our_w<strong>ork</strong>/democracy_and_governance/publications/pdfs/pnacr220.pdf._____. 2006. Administrative <strong>Law</strong> and Procedural Systems (<strong>AL</strong>PS)Re<strong>for</strong>m in Bosnia and Herzegovina, 3rd Annual Report,available at http://www.usaid.ba/Assessments/Admin%20<strong>Law</strong>%20Assessments/IRIS_<strong>AL</strong>PS%202005%20Annual%20Report.doc.Van Rooij, B. 2007. Bringing Justice to <strong>the</strong> Poor: Bottom-up LegalDevelopment Cooperation, W<strong>ork</strong>ing paper available athttp://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTJUSFORPOOR/Resources/VanRooijBringingJusticeto<strong>the</strong>Poor.pdfVigoda, E. 2002. ‘From Responsiveness to Collaboration: Governance,Citizens, and <strong>the</strong> Next Generation of Public Administration.’Public Administration Review. 62: 527-538.Wojkowska, E. 2006. Doing Justice: How In<strong>for</strong>mal Justice Systems CanContribute (UNDP, Oslo Governance Centre), available athttp://www.undp.org/oslocentre/docs07/DoingJusticeEwa-Wojkowska130307.pdf.World Bank. 2007. ‘Promoting <strong>the</strong> Right of Egyptian Woman To ClaimTheir Identity and Their Futures.’ Development MarketplaceProject Stories. Available at http://go.worldbank.org/3DKFL6QT90._____. 1997. ‘Restraining Arbitrary State Action and Corruption.’ In:World Development Report. Washington, D.C.: Ox<strong>for</strong>d UniversityPress.Yeazell, S. 2006, ‘Socializing <strong>Law</strong>, Privatizing <strong>Law</strong>, Monopolizing<strong>Law</strong>, Accessing <strong>Law</strong>.’ Loyola of Los Angeles <strong>Law</strong> Review.39(2):691-717.61


ChapterTWOEmpowering <strong>the</strong>Poor ThroughProperty Rights63


EXECUTIVE SUMMARYProperty Rights are Human Rights‘<strong>Everyone</strong> has <strong>the</strong> right to own property alone as well as in association with o<strong>the</strong>rs … .No one shall be arbitrarily deprived of his property.’ 1Property rights must be understood as afundamental human right. 2 The body andmind are <strong>the</strong> first and most immediateproperty of persons and thus respect <strong>for</strong> thisproperty is related to <strong>the</strong> respect of <strong>the</strong> integrityof <strong>the</strong> individual. 3 Throughout history <strong>the</strong> ideaof human rights has developed in close associationwith <strong>the</strong> idea of private property rights. 4Early defenders of human rights consideredproperty rights as important as freedom of religionand freedom of speech. But <strong>the</strong> majority of<strong>the</strong> world’s population does not have adequateaccess to secure property rights, and <strong>the</strong>ir realisationremains an arena <strong>for</strong> social and politicalcontestation.Absence of Property Rights andPovertyThe absence or insecurity of property rights is acentral and ubiquitous cause of poverty, not onlyin <strong>the</strong> very poorest states, but also in middleincomecountries such as Brazil, Russia, Indiaand China. 5 The relationship between absence ofproperty rights and poverty is moving from argumentand anecdote to comparative analysis andmeasurement. Secure property rights facilitateeconomic transactions, ensure efficient and sustainableresource use, allow <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> evolution ofeffective credit markets, improve business climateand investment opportunities, and ensure economicaccountability and transparency. Equally,<strong>the</strong> absence of such rights undermines economicdevelopment and hinders governance. Analysis of<strong>the</strong> World Bank’s Country Per<strong>for</strong>mance and InstitutionalAssessment (CPIA) ratings <strong>for</strong> 2005 indicatesthat on a scale of 1 to 6 (with 1 being <strong>the</strong>lowest score), only five of 76 developing countriesscored 4 on objective measurement of propertyrights and rule-based governance. 6 As all five aresmall island states, this indication confirms thatproperty rights of <strong>the</strong> absolute majority of <strong>the</strong> peoplein developing countries are not protected in<strong>the</strong>ory or practice, contracts are not en<strong>for</strong>ced, andregistries and o<strong>the</strong>r institutions required to protectproperty function poorly or not at all. 7Especially Vulnerable GroupsCertain groups are frequently and systematicallydisenfranchised through lack of access to propertyrights in many countries. Women, who constitutehalf of <strong>the</strong> world’s population, own around10 percent of <strong>the</strong> world’s property. 8 Virginia Woolfeloquently expressed <strong>the</strong> long arch of history thathas not only excluded women from property in64


<strong>the</strong> West, but that has made entire state institutionsmasculine preserves. 9 Even when womenhave de jure property rights, <strong>the</strong>ir de facto controlof land is tenuous, and men largely mediatedaccess. In Imo and Abia states in Nigeria, <strong>for</strong>example, average household farms are 9.8 hectares,of which only 2.4 hectares are allocatedto women. However, this land is not a claim, butra<strong>the</strong>r a lease, which women must organise from<strong>the</strong>ir husbands. Fur<strong>the</strong>r, widows cannot own land;<strong>the</strong>ir husband’s family keep it in trust <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>irchildren. 10 As Robin Nielsen has pointed out:‘At various stages in women’s lives, <strong>the</strong>ir rightsto land are dependent on fa<strong>the</strong>rs, bro<strong>the</strong>rs, husbandsand sons. A more precarious foundation <strong>for</strong>land rights is difficult to imagine.’ 11 Ensuring thatwomen’s names appear on land records, that <strong>the</strong>irrights are enshrined in communal property systems,and that inheritance rights of widows anddaughters are established and protected, wouldgo a long way towards improving <strong>the</strong>ir condition.This is essential to empowerment and <strong>the</strong> promotionof entrepreneurial activity and should beplaced at <strong>the</strong> centre of property re<strong>for</strong>m ef<strong>for</strong>ts.Equally, indigenous people around <strong>the</strong> world tendto suffer from weak or prescribed property rightsnot adequately recognised by law. These groupsoften hold land collectively, so ownership andaccess patterns do not always fit easily into imported,non-indigenous property systems of absoluteand individual nature. As <strong>the</strong>y are largelydisenfranchised, <strong>the</strong> customary land rights of <strong>the</strong>indigenous tend to be overlooked. The AbayandaPygmies in Uganda, <strong>for</strong> example, have beenentirely dispossessed of <strong>the</strong>ir land; <strong>the</strong>y haveendured persistent lack of recognition by <strong>the</strong>central government of legitimate claims to <strong>the</strong>irproperty. Indeed, <strong>the</strong> problem is far from solvedin developed countries. In 1902, Norway passedlegislation requiring full knowledge of <strong>the</strong> Norwegianlanguage <strong>for</strong> property ownership, effectivelymaking it impossible <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> indigenous Sami toown land.In 2004 an International Labour Organisation(ILO) expert committee concluded that an Actpassed in 2003 to rectify centuries of exclusionarypractices still did not meet <strong>the</strong> minimumstandards <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> ILO convention on <strong>the</strong> rights ofindigenous and tribal peoples. 12 Global re<strong>for</strong>mof property rights regimes must allow <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>malrecognition of customary land rights as <strong>the</strong> basis<strong>for</strong> inclusive property systems that include indigenouspeoples. There are some good examplesin The Commonwealth Native Title Act of 1993in Australia, and <strong>the</strong> landmark Te Ture WhenuaMaori Act in New Zealand, both of which respect<strong>the</strong> customary land rights of indigenous groups.Although time will tell if laws of this nature canchange deeply entrenched exclusionary practices,but legal empowerment <strong>for</strong> poor indigenousgroups will certainly remain key to tackling thischallenge in both OECD and developing countries.Urban slum dwellers are also excluded from<strong>for</strong>mal property systems. At least a third of <strong>the</strong>world’s poor, or a billion people, are living inslums without legal protection of <strong>the</strong>ir assets. 13Ironically, it is often insecurity of land tenureand wrongful loss of land in rural areas that encourage<strong>the</strong> poor to escape, while <strong>the</strong>ir propertyrights in urban areas are no less tenuous. Thereality of urban slum dwellers is sub-standardhousing conditions, <strong>for</strong>ceful evictions, extortion,social exclusion, and environmental degradation,among o<strong>the</strong>r problems. The situation preventsdevelopment of adequate housing stock and <strong>the</strong>emergence of robust property and credit markets.In<strong>for</strong>mal property systems are often perpetuatedin conflict-affected countries by flows of refugeesand Internally Displaced Persons (IDPs) from ru-65


al to urban areas, and this leads to fur<strong>the</strong>r insecurityand overcrowding.Legal access to property rights <strong>for</strong> various groupsis clearly an over-arching and universal issuethat should be at <strong>the</strong> centre of global ef<strong>for</strong>ts toempower <strong>the</strong> poor; but it has in fact received verylittle coherent analysis to date. To unpack <strong>the</strong>relationship between poverty and property rightswe must understand that it is <strong>the</strong>se rights thatprovide <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>for</strong> economic growth. The globaleconomy grew very slowly until <strong>the</strong> beginning of<strong>the</strong> 19 th Century. Be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong>n, and <strong>for</strong> thousandsof years, notes Jeffrey Sachs, ‘<strong>the</strong>re had beenvirtually no sustained economic growth in <strong>the</strong>world’. 14 However, with <strong>the</strong> advent of <strong>the</strong> industrialrevolution and economic expansion, assetsexpanded and property rights evolved. Slowly <strong>the</strong>idea of private property ownership came to underpineconomic development in <strong>the</strong> West. Whilesocial, economic and political stability was upsetby two World Wars and <strong>the</strong> Great Depression, <strong>the</strong>GI Bill of Rights in <strong>the</strong> United States, <strong>the</strong> MarshallPlan and <strong>the</strong> incipient economic and politicalunion in Europe, and rapid development inEast Asia supported <strong>the</strong> growth of a middle-classthat led to fur<strong>the</strong>r consolidation of legal propertysystems in <strong>the</strong>se regions. The trans<strong>for</strong>mation frompredominantly extralegal property systems to <strong>for</strong>malproperty rights entrenched in law has sincecome to support functioning market economiesand polities.The Building Blocks of <strong>the</strong> PropertySystemThis transition has reduced global poverty substantially,but as outlined above, billions of peoplearound <strong>the</strong> world still lack secure propertyrights, which hinders <strong>the</strong>ir economic, politicaland social security. In order to examine how povertycan best be relieved, and why access to propertyrights is fundamental to <strong>the</strong> empowermentof <strong>the</strong> poor, it is necessary to identify buildingblocks of a fully-functional property system. Sucha system operates in <strong>the</strong> following four ways:1) As a system of rules that defines <strong>the</strong> bundleof rights and obligations between people andassets. 15 Property ownership creates ties thatbind individual citizens toge<strong>the</strong>r through <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mation of netw<strong>ork</strong>s of economic and legalrights and corresponding obligations. Thecredible en<strong>for</strong>cement of <strong>the</strong>se rights and obligationsrequires a judicial mechanism thatallows <strong>for</strong> equitable, transparent and efficientdispute resolution.2) As a system of governance. Property systemsare a central facet of state functionality, andas such are an important measurement of fiduciaryand administrative effectiveness. Theinstitutional order of <strong>the</strong> state is based ontechnical rules and relationships which defineinteractions between stakeholders, rangingfrom direct ownership of land to promulgationof rules that govern security of land andhouse tenure, land planning, zoning, taxingand o<strong>the</strong>r aspects of property management.Technological innovation, which has radicallyreduced <strong>the</strong> cost of in<strong>for</strong>mation, has generated<strong>the</strong> possibility <strong>for</strong> fur<strong>the</strong>r transparency and accountabilityin property systems as an instrumentof governance.3) As a functioning market <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> exchange ofassets. A fully functional property system allowsland, houses, moveable property, equityshares, and ideas to be trans<strong>for</strong>med into assetsto be bought and sold at rates determinedby market <strong>for</strong>ces. This subjects <strong>the</strong> exchangeof property to a level of transparency and accountability,and allows <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> developmentof financial mechanisms — including credit66


and insurance — to facilitate transactions andimprove economic outcomes. Land, housesand moveable property can thus be leveraged,and assets trans<strong>for</strong>med from static investmentsinto capital which can be bought andsold. However, property rights are a necessarybut not sufficient precondition <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> developmentof <strong>the</strong>se financial mechanisms; <strong>the</strong>yalso develop through partnership between <strong>the</strong>market, special funds targeted at access tofinance, and <strong>the</strong> state.4) As an instrument of social policy. In <strong>the</strong> absenceor failure of <strong>the</strong> market, <strong>the</strong> state oftenplays a direct role in addressing <strong>the</strong> needs of<strong>the</strong> poor. The state has at its disposal instrumentsthat can be used to endow its citizenswith assets as <strong>the</strong>y relate to property, suchas public housing, low interest loans and <strong>the</strong>distribution of state land. Such instrumentshelp to overcome natural competition <strong>for</strong> assets.The state also supports social cohesionthrough <strong>the</strong> development of co-ownership ofinfrastructure and services by government and<strong>the</strong> citizen, supporting <strong>the</strong> equilibrium betweenindividual and collective interests. Provisionof infrastructure by <strong>the</strong> state criticallyaffects <strong>the</strong> value and desirability of assets,and can <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e fundamentally affect opportunities<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor.Dysfunctionalities in PropertyManagementThese four key building blocks can be viewed as acoherent framew<strong>ork</strong> through which to understandproperty rights. It follows that analysis of <strong>the</strong>seblocks allows us to identify where dysfunctionalitiesin property management might arise andwhere <strong>the</strong>re are disconnects within key elementsof this framew<strong>ork</strong>. As far as <strong>the</strong> poor are concerned,<strong>the</strong>y have trouble getting property in <strong>the</strong>first place (unfairly limited access). Where <strong>the</strong>yhave assets, <strong>the</strong>ir rights are often not adequatelyrecognised, or en<strong>for</strong>ced, or given full backing of<strong>the</strong> law, and are consequently vulnerable to beinglost. Unfairly limited access to property and insecurityof assets are caused by dysfunctionalitiesin <strong>the</strong> property system that can be understoodfourfold:1) Misalignment of social practice and legalprovision. Social practice and law rein<strong>for</strong>ceeach o<strong>the</strong>r when aligned towards commonobjectives, but when misaligned can underminestate legitimacy and accountability andweaken ties of citizenship. <strong>Law</strong> must evolveorganically to suit <strong>the</strong> context in which it is tobe applied and should not be perceived as <strong>the</strong>instrument through which a minority imposesits power. Legal aspects of property systemsmust grow from land practices on <strong>the</strong> groundand incorporate customary interactions andnetw<strong>ork</strong>s. There have been two common sourcesof misalignment. Firstly, some states, particularlyduring <strong>the</strong> colonial period, imposedproperty systems on vast tracts of land thatwere previously regulated through customaryregimes of rights and obligations. The resultwas a major gap between daily practices of <strong>the</strong>people and requirements of <strong>for</strong>mal law. Secondly,in urban areas, as de Soto has pointedout, ill-conceived laws have <strong>for</strong>ced millions ofpeople into in<strong>for</strong>mality, as gaining access toland <strong>for</strong> housing is a lengthy process, measuredin terms of years if not decades. 162) Misuse of rules governing property. While rules<strong>for</strong> property systems may be both appropriateand equitable, <strong>the</strong>y may still be open toabuse by those in power. Rules are resourcesthat can be subverted to serve <strong>the</strong> interests of<strong>the</strong> few, through corruption and lack of transparency,ra<strong>the</strong>r than acting as a framew<strong>ork</strong>67


<strong>for</strong> empowerment of <strong>the</strong> many. Equally, landregulations, ra<strong>the</strong>r than providing a framew<strong>ork</strong>within which parameters <strong>for</strong> property managementare set and transactions enabled, canbecome mechanisms <strong>for</strong> restriction of propertyrights and bureaucratic mismanagement.3) Lack of access to in<strong>for</strong>mation and justice.Even where cadastres, land registers and o<strong>the</strong>rrepositories of property titles, records anddocuments exist, restriction of access to suchin<strong>for</strong>mation reduces <strong>the</strong> transparency and efficiencyof property transactions. Governmentsmust w<strong>ork</strong> to make in<strong>for</strong>mation on propertyavailable to <strong>the</strong> general public and seek tocollect fur<strong>the</strong>r data and opinion in innovativeways through <strong>the</strong> promotion of opportunities<strong>for</strong> public debate on property and citizen resourcerights, and streng<strong>the</strong>ning of knowledgesharing and analysis on <strong>the</strong>se issues.4) Misuse of eminent domain. Corrupt governmentscan use <strong>the</strong> inherent power of <strong>the</strong> stateto seize private property and thus confiscateassets of <strong>the</strong> poor in <strong>the</strong> name of <strong>the</strong> publicgood. The primary remedy against wrongfulor unjust loss of property is a just policy ofland acquisition and resettlement; it can includeinnovative approaches, such as offeringpartnerships to <strong>the</strong> poor in developing assetscreated from investment in infrastructure andservices. International financial institutions,particularly <strong>the</strong> World Bank and <strong>the</strong> AsianDevelopment Bank, moved systematically inthis way in <strong>the</strong> 1990s to address <strong>the</strong> adverseimpacts that developmental projects had on<strong>the</strong> standard of living of <strong>the</strong> poor. At <strong>the</strong> nationallevel, however, practices differ widelyand abuse, with regard to use of eminent domain(<strong>for</strong> depriving <strong>the</strong> poor of <strong>the</strong>ir assets),continues to be a problem. Re<strong>for</strong>m of compulsoryacquisition mechanisms is necessary,as demonstrated most palpably in Zimbabwerecently, one of <strong>the</strong> few countries today whichconstitutionally permits appropriation withoutpayment of any compensation. 17 Review of 20land acquisition laws in Sub-Saharan Africa 18indicates three sources of this type of legaldisempowerment: (1) process of acquisition,wherein, <strong>for</strong> example, compensation valuingbillions of dollars remains unpaid in someregions without clear avenues of redress; (2)<strong>the</strong> basis <strong>for</strong> compensation payment, whichroutinely fails to take into account real coststo <strong>the</strong> loss of land, and (3) manipulation,through purposeful or poorly specified definition,of what constitutes ‘public purpose’. 19Property Rights and LegalEmpowermentProperty rights are defined through law, and<strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> poor, ascitizens, can only come about through <strong>the</strong> protectionof those rights. However, legal status canhave strikingly different impacts upon citizenship:it can become an instrument <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> creation ofopportunities <strong>for</strong> exercising rights, create entitlementsto rights <strong>for</strong> specific categories of people,or repress or deny contestation of those rights too<strong>the</strong>rs. H.L.A. Hart’s distinction between internaland external views of <strong>the</strong> law shown in Table 1 isinstructive. 20Since internal actors are positioned in a hierarchy,<strong>the</strong> extent to which legal status producesloyalty to <strong>the</strong> social order depends on feedbackloops. ‘Loops’ between and among <strong>the</strong> actors affect<strong>the</strong> degree of efficiency and effectiveness of<strong>the</strong> administrators in delivering rights or en<strong>for</strong>cingobligations in a manner that incorporates accountability.The ‘user’ perspective is essential <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>legitimacy of <strong>the</strong> system, as legitimacy is <strong>the</strong> outcomeof <strong>the</strong> degree to which people, once granted68


Table 1 Mapping <strong>the</strong> dynamics of legal statusExternalThe public, social movementsLegal community of practiceJudicial Review, civil society and mediaExcluded/ineligible peopleInternalThe authorizing environment <strong>for</strong> rule-making (Parliament, Congress,Cabinet Board of Corporations)Composers/Drafters (Constitutions, primary, secondarylegislation, by-laws, manuals)Administrators/OrganisersUsers/citizensa particular legal status or set of rights, such asproperty rights, come to identify and endorse <strong>the</strong>social order so produced. External actors are positionedto push <strong>the</strong> frontiers of <strong>the</strong> existing socialorder by questioning <strong>the</strong> balance between solidarityand inequality. They catalyse changes to existingcitizenship arrangements, in questioning <strong>the</strong>fairness or effectiveness of an existing legal status,and in <strong>the</strong> creation of new legal status <strong>for</strong> specificgroups. The creation and expansion of citizenshiprights is a process of contestation that can lead tonew interpretations of old laws and <strong>the</strong> promulgationof new laws, or <strong>the</strong> creation of new mechanismsto deal with issues that do not fit into anexisting framew<strong>ork</strong>. Thus, groups that question <strong>the</strong>status quo can prove that <strong>the</strong> law is malleable, justas indigenous groups have fought <strong>for</strong>, and won,recognition of customary land rights in Australia orNew Zealand.However, <strong>the</strong> provision of property rights inlaw does not always guarantee equality inpractice. While states can attempt to balanceinequality and solidarity, discrimination and socialclassifications remain entrenched in manysocieties. Inequality can stem from deep-rootedcultural distinctions such as caste, gender andrace, and <strong>the</strong> challenge <strong>the</strong>n is to create conditions<strong>for</strong> property rights not just at <strong>the</strong> legal level,but through mechanisms that can fundamentallychange mental models and social practices at alllevels of society. Even in <strong>the</strong> European Union,where equality of men and women is a fundamentalaxiom of policy, gender mainstreaming insocial policy still remains a significant challenge,according to a recent European Commission reporton social inclusion. 21The degree to which an order is open or closed, toextending legal status to new groups or to changing<strong>the</strong> status of existing groups, is an importanttest of its capacity <strong>for</strong> coping with change. Evenwhen creation of status is open in <strong>the</strong>ory, mechanismsare needed to create trust in <strong>the</strong> socialorder. If property rights are legally extended toa previously disenfranchised group, that groupmust believe that <strong>the</strong>ir property will not be seizedthrough misuse of eminent domain.There<strong>for</strong>e, context-based legal re<strong>for</strong>m is critical togovernance in developing countries. There can beno blanket approach: expansion of property rightsin a coherent manner requires understanding oftrends and a tailoring of provisions to context.There must be a degree of coherence to lawsbased on fundamental rules, or those laws willnot be respected. If de jure property rights do notcorrespond with de facto property practices andcustoms, <strong>the</strong> subsequent legal misalignment willundermine ra<strong>the</strong>r than streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> system.Disorder and dysfunction has its own stakeholders,and if resources are seen as zero-sum,change can be perceived as highly threatening byentrenched interests.69


Property systems consist of a bundle of rights andobligations. In OECD countries, an entire seriesof legal innovations has evolved to allow <strong>for</strong> cooperativearrangements that underpin this dynamicand support transparent, effective property-basedeconomies. The same type of thinking has notbeen applied to developing-country contexts toexamine precisely how property arrangementscould be modified, and interactions codified, inways that would allow <strong>the</strong> poor to leverage <strong>the</strong>irassets and become legitimate stakeholders inglobal property systems. Urban slums representland that could be a valuable asset when conceptualizedin a different way as part of coherenturban planning strategies. Latent assets mustbe leveraged and <strong>the</strong>ir stakeholders — <strong>the</strong> poor— brought into dynamic new partnerships toalign law and practice in ways that allow <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>systemic expansion of property rights.Key Elements of a Re<strong>for</strong>m StrategyThis process creates both a national and globalpublic good, and to bring it about governmentsof developing countries must enter into adouble compact - with <strong>the</strong>ir citizens and <strong>the</strong> internationalcommunity. To level <strong>the</strong> playing field <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor and operate in a manner that best serves<strong>the</strong> interests of <strong>the</strong> disenfranchised, internationalactors must develop long-term partnerships withnational governments on property rights as partof <strong>the</strong> broader economic governance agenda. Are<strong>for</strong>m strategy <strong>for</strong> effectively functioning propertysystems that empower <strong>the</strong> poor should be basedon land tenure security, creation of opportunity <strong>for</strong>investment, and adequate management of risk.The elements of such a strategy must:1) Promote Legitimacy by Adequate Participationand Deliberation. In general, future re<strong>for</strong>m willrequire a legitimate state. For implementationat all levels, re<strong>for</strong>ms must be based ondeliberation and inputs from those that <strong>the</strong>yare intended to affect. This will bring focus onrelevant issues, engender acceptance by localcommunities, and reduce <strong>the</strong> cost of re<strong>for</strong>m.In Peru between 1996 and 2000, <strong>for</strong> example,3,500 meetings were held on land titling processesin different settlements around <strong>the</strong> country,helping to improve community satisfactionwith property re<strong>for</strong>m ef<strong>for</strong>ts. 22 In particular, <strong>the</strong>groups outlined above - women, indigenousgroups, and urban slum dwellers - and o<strong>the</strong>rexcluded groups, must be given special attentionas part of this process. Support <strong>for</strong> initiativessuch as <strong>the</strong> establishment of coalitionsbetween urban and rural poor around commonconcerns including <strong>the</strong> effects of <strong>the</strong> rural exoduson rural economies and urban poverty are aproductive starting point. 232) Support Parallel Interventions. Implementationof rules that underpin a functioning system <strong>for</strong>access to, and registration of, property, do notautomatically create <strong>the</strong> mechanisms necessaryto support this system. By giving attention to<strong>the</strong> four building blocks of <strong>the</strong> property system,governments must carefully plan and sequence<strong>the</strong> interventions that will create <strong>the</strong> corollaryfinancial and legal instruments that underpineffective property rights and facilitate accessto managerial ability, technology, credit, andmarkets <strong>for</strong> new property owners to becomecompetitive. The evolution of efficient financialmarkets will depend on <strong>the</strong> ability to use land,and o<strong>the</strong>r property, as collateral. In developedcountries, more than two thirds of small businessloans are secured against land and realestate. Experience in South Africa and Brazildemonstrates that unconventional avenues(e.g. partnerships and joint ventures with oldland owners) may be a useful first step. Governmentsshould also develop methods <strong>for</strong> in-70


creasing finance <strong>for</strong> land re<strong>for</strong>m and post-landacquisition services, including land banks,land-<strong>for</strong>-debt schemes and land <strong>for</strong> taxes. 243) Facilitate Private Sector Involvement. Thestate needs to set <strong>the</strong> parameters within whichprivate sector investment can take place, andremove any disincentives to this process. Fees<strong>for</strong> property transactions, which in some developingcountries can be as high as 30 percent,act as an unnecessary <strong>for</strong>m of taxation thatinhibits <strong>the</strong> free exchange of land throughmarket mechanisms and excludes <strong>the</strong> poor.Official land taxes must also be set at an af<strong>for</strong>dablelevel <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor and subsidies andtax provisions that provide distorting privilegesto large-scale farmers should be removed. InMexico, <strong>for</strong> example, certain groups ‘prefer notto regularise <strong>the</strong> land <strong>for</strong> human settlementto evade having to paying land tax, which promotesin<strong>for</strong>mality in land markets.’ 25 Investmentclimate surveys indicate that access toland was <strong>the</strong> main obstacle to conducting andexpanding business by 57 percent of <strong>the</strong> enterprisesinterviewed in Ethiopia, 35 percentin Bangladesh and 25 percent in Tanzania andKenya.4) Promote Property Rights through Individualand Corporate Ownership. Property law shouldoffer clear and simple options of legal personalityand corporate ownership <strong>for</strong> smallbusinesses and corporative associations of <strong>the</strong>poor. Legal personality so designed opens upa wide range of possibilities of ownership byhuman individuals, by members of collectives,and by collectives. Pro-poor property rights systemsfacilitate <strong>the</strong> ability of people to pool andleverage modest resources and limit liabilitiesin case of business failure or exit of partners.One of <strong>the</strong> keys to economic success of smallentrepreneurs in <strong>the</strong> developing world is <strong>the</strong>limited liability of business owners, thus offering<strong>the</strong> possibility of controlled failure withoutdisastrous economic consequences <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>vulnerable individuals involved. This legal instrumentof limited corporate liability has to beextended to <strong>the</strong> poor micro-entrepreneurs andrural producers. It constitutes one of <strong>the</strong> mainadvantages of <strong>for</strong>mality of corporate ownershipand can trump unavoidable disadvantages.5) Create Systems <strong>for</strong> Collateralising Moveableand Intangible Property. Although many of <strong>the</strong>citizens of <strong>the</strong> developing world lack securerights to use and transfer real property, mostof <strong>the</strong>m own some tangible (moveable) or intangibleproperty. 26 To <strong>the</strong> extent that this typeof property is held securely and can be used toaccess credit and to create and grow businesses,<strong>the</strong> poor will have increased opportunities.Experience in a variety of developing countries(Georgia, Madagascar, Colombia, Albania, Bosniaamong <strong>the</strong>m) suggests that <strong>the</strong>re are importantlegal re<strong>for</strong>ms that would allow <strong>the</strong> poorto leverage movable and intangible property.6) Co-management of Natural Resources. The majorityof <strong>the</strong> rural poor depend to a large extenton non-arable resources such as <strong>for</strong>ests, pastures,swamplands, and fishing grounds. Theseresources require careful management to avoidrent-seeking and corrupt practices that resultin environmental degradation and economicinefficiencies. The state should enhance <strong>the</strong>asset base of <strong>the</strong> poor by enabling communitybasedownership and management of privatecommons, but it will have to play <strong>the</strong> role ofconflict manager among <strong>the</strong> communities andamong individuals. In <strong>the</strong> case of fossil energyresources requiring capital intensive extraction,treatment and distribution, <strong>the</strong> state shouldutilise transparent and fair auction procedureswhen involving <strong>the</strong> private sector, linked to71


conditionality of local community development.These procedures could be regulatedand implemented on <strong>the</strong> basis of multilateralcharters. 27 In <strong>the</strong> case of state co-ownershipof fossil energy reserves, <strong>the</strong> local populationsshould be included in <strong>the</strong> chain of value additionby tradable shares in general public funds.Distributing among <strong>the</strong> poor shares or o<strong>the</strong>r<strong>for</strong>ms of ownership participation in state ownedcompanies that exploit <strong>the</strong> natural resourceswill provide <strong>the</strong>m with capital that, inter alia,can propel <strong>the</strong> expansion of small businesses.Ano<strong>the</strong>r option is distributing titles to specialfunds created by governments to invest profitsyielded by commodities. 287) Utilise Modern Technology. Manual systemsof land registration are highly labour intensiveand lead to significant error and duplication.Moreover, <strong>the</strong> costs of manual land survey andregistration processes are often prohibitive.Recent advances in technology, including <strong>the</strong>widespread availability of satellite imageryand handheld GPS devices, toge<strong>the</strong>r with institutionalarrangements that put local actorsin charge of systematic adjudication, can significantlyreduce <strong>the</strong> cost and ef<strong>for</strong>t of issuingland registration documents. Moreover, moderntechnology can help to improve transparencyand at <strong>the</strong> same time make land administrationmore accessible. 29 There are caveatsto this process, identified in <strong>the</strong> report.Based on <strong>the</strong>se principles, developing countrygovernments, supported by <strong>the</strong> internationalcommunity, must devise a series of innovative,pro-poor land re<strong>for</strong>m policies that are distinctlyfocused on ensuring that more of <strong>the</strong> benefits ofproperty systems accrue to those at <strong>the</strong> very bottomof <strong>the</strong> economic ladder. A careful stocktakingof such ef<strong>for</strong>ts already underway in various partsof <strong>the</strong> world, including analysis of conditions thatgave rise to such ef<strong>for</strong>ts, and possibilities <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>irexpansion, will be instructive. We can developtransitional re<strong>for</strong>m mechanisms from experiencein <strong>the</strong> Philippines, <strong>for</strong> example, where <strong>the</strong> nationalgovernment employs intermediate instruments ofland tenure, such as land proclamations, to assure<strong>the</strong> poor that <strong>the</strong>y will not be evicted fromland <strong>the</strong>y occupy, and that social services will beimproved while plot ownership is <strong>for</strong>malised. 30Or we consider how <strong>the</strong> South African experiencewith Mzansi accounts, providing low-fee banking<strong>for</strong> poor people w<strong>ork</strong>ing in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector,could be replicated elsewhere. 31 Modalities exist toempower <strong>the</strong> poor through property rights, but wemust now scale up and catalyse <strong>the</strong>m.ConclusionLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor through propertyrights requires sustained ef<strong>for</strong>ts. Property systemsthat exclude large segments of <strong>the</strong> global populationfrom property rights have to be discontinuedand we must expand <strong>the</strong> zone of legitimate landtenure through improved access and security.Developing country governments must enter intoa compact with <strong>the</strong>ir own citizens and with <strong>the</strong>international community to support this re<strong>for</strong>m.The aid community understands that propertyrights must be a central tenet of any ef<strong>for</strong>ts toreduce poverty, and allocates funding on thisbasis. Today, <strong>the</strong> key challenge is to consolidatethinking and draw good practice from effectiveinterventions to date to improve pro-poor outcomes,develop effective land management institutions,establish clear rules <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> managementof public land, and streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> institutionalframew<strong>ork</strong> and mechanisms <strong>for</strong> land transfer andaccess. Property rights are too central to humandignity and prosperity <strong>for</strong> current thinking andpractice to continue. Only with empowermentthrough property rights can we truly seek to reduceglobal poverty and reduce inequality.72


I. IntroductionAs <strong>the</strong>se lines are being written, close to30,000 of India’s roughly 170 million landlesspeople are marching peacefully to Delhion <strong>the</strong> highway. They demand not to be drivenoff <strong>the</strong>ir land just because it was declared stateproperty; <strong>the</strong>y demand property documents or <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mal registration of documents in <strong>the</strong>ir possession;<strong>the</strong>y demanded that unused state land beallocated to <strong>the</strong>m, and <strong>the</strong>y demand state protectionagainst violent guerrilla movements. Thefulfilment of <strong>the</strong>se demands, and <strong>the</strong> solution tomany o<strong>the</strong>r property-related problems identifiedin this report, requires strong, sustained and context-basedre<strong>for</strong>m. Such re<strong>for</strong>m has to be foundedin political will and <strong>the</strong> associational power of <strong>the</strong>poor, exemplified by <strong>the</strong> marchers in India.Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor is a framew<strong>ork</strong>of action which takes such demands seriously.It recommends <strong>the</strong> promotion of domestic legaland administrative framew<strong>ork</strong>s providing <strong>the</strong> pooropportunities to use <strong>the</strong>ir talents and to trans<strong>for</strong>m<strong>the</strong>ir impressive economic ef<strong>for</strong>ts into anincreased and secured asset base. The agendaimplies a general re<strong>for</strong>m of <strong>the</strong> law from an instrumentof domination into a system of effectiveprotections and opportunities <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor. 32On <strong>the</strong> input side, <strong>the</strong> emphasis of legal empowermentis placed on participatory and accountable<strong>for</strong>ms of law-making and public administration,giving voice to <strong>the</strong> poor and increasedownership of <strong>the</strong> framing of <strong>the</strong>ir legal and socialenvironment. Regarding <strong>the</strong> means, legal empowermentstresses <strong>the</strong> critical importance of<strong>the</strong> following: granting legal identity and accessto justice to all human persons, small businesscorporations, and civil society associations (seeChapter 1 of this report); securing property rightsof <strong>the</strong> poor as asset holders through comprehensiveand context-based property rights systems;protecting <strong>the</strong> poor as w<strong>ork</strong>ers (see Chapter 3),and creating an enabling business environment<strong>for</strong> small entrepreneurs and <strong>the</strong> self-employed(Chapter 4). On <strong>the</strong> output side, a result-orientedlegal empowerment agenda stresses effectiveprotection of livelihoods of <strong>the</strong> poor and, moreoriginally, measurable creation of new opportunities<strong>for</strong> diversifying livelihoods, <strong>the</strong>reby improvinglives. Escape from <strong>the</strong> poverty trap and creating amore decent life are seen as <strong>the</strong> principal aims.Property rights stand <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> bundle of libertiesand claim rights tied to <strong>the</strong> allocation of aresource to a natural or legal person, corporation,collectivity, association, etc. The concept of propertyrights as human rights and as part of LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor implies two agendas:legally en<strong>for</strong>ced protection of <strong>the</strong> assets of <strong>the</strong>poor, and general promotion of access to propertyby <strong>the</strong> poor.Through sustainable ownership and/or securityof tenure 33 individuals and communities becomemore autonomous. Even with modest assets, asholders of property rights, individuals and groupsbecome more active as independent members of<strong>the</strong>ir communities and nations. Private propertyrights allow people to pool <strong>the</strong>ir assets into transparentstructures of co-ownership with fair exitoptions. This is critical <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor who have veryfew assets but who can achieve social and economicleverage by pooling assets into legally recognisedcommon or community property. Reliableand equitable property rights systems help settlecompeting property claims and facilitate <strong>the</strong>identification of responsibilities and liabilities.The increased social stability and trust emanatingfrom robust property rights systems create appropriateenvironments <strong>for</strong> business and investment.Secure rights to use and trade property providestrong incentives to maintain and conserve re-73


sources. Individuals and groups with such rightstend to invest in <strong>the</strong> resources <strong>the</strong>y hold. In general,property rights give people a horizon to plan<strong>the</strong> future <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>mselves and <strong>the</strong>ir communities.Structure and Goal of this ChapterNone of <strong>the</strong> above-mentioned benefits can beachieved easily with one-size-fits-all models. Thischapter elaborates <strong>the</strong> main features of re<strong>for</strong>mwith a special but non-exclusive emphasis on<strong>the</strong> poor. Section 2 identifies <strong>the</strong> most vulnerablesegments of society and <strong>the</strong> relation of <strong>the</strong>irpoverty and exclusion to <strong>the</strong> problem of propertyrights protection. Section 3 briefly assesses <strong>the</strong>barriers and facilitators of change, drawing attentionto social actors as well as structural conditionsfavouring status quo or change, while Section4 contains a concise compilation of lessonsand experienced consequences of past re<strong>for</strong>mactivities, and prepares <strong>the</strong> ground <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> maindiscussion, in Section 5, on proposals within <strong>the</strong>four building blocks of <strong>the</strong> property system. Theproposals aim at re<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>the</strong> property system(viewed as an arrangement of rules defining orenabling bundles and bearers of property rights)in such a manner that it would enable <strong>the</strong> poor— especially women and indigenous communities— to access and to secure property. The suggestionsshould also help to re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> propertysystem so it could serve as a <strong>for</strong>m of governance,as a functioning market of assets (including <strong>the</strong>poor in <strong>the</strong> chains of value addition), and as asystem of social policy with targeted measuresof capacity building and access to property andhousing.Parallel re<strong>for</strong>m w<strong>ork</strong>, sustained by constantmonitoring in all four dimensions, is advocatedin order to achieve real progress. Common<strong>for</strong>mal features of policy design and prioritisingare dealt with in a special paragraph of Section5. The establishment of fully functional propertysystems and positive effects <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor is firstand <strong>for</strong>emost a national and local re<strong>for</strong>m issuedemanding <strong>the</strong> renegotiation of institutional, legal,and social relations at <strong>the</strong> national and locallevel. However, an additional section of this reportalso points to important subsidiary and stabilisingaction by donor countries and multilateralarrangements.This chapter deals with <strong>the</strong> most general featuresof pro-poor property re<strong>for</strong>m and is thus not to beread as a national or local implementation report.It builds, however, on lessons and practices thathave proven beneficial in many different contextsand that have been highlighted in numerous nationaland grass roots consultations of <strong>the</strong> CLEP.Our recommendations, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, deserve to beseriously considered and fur<strong>the</strong>r tailored to local-realitycontext by property rights re<strong>for</strong>m in <strong>the</strong>developing world.Although not repeatedly mentioned throughoutthis chapter, <strong>the</strong> members of our w<strong>ork</strong>ing groupacknowledge <strong>the</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>ts of numerous governments,international organisations, and NGOs in<strong>the</strong> field of property rights. And as many membersare <strong>the</strong>mselves part of past and ongoing ef<strong>for</strong>tsin <strong>the</strong> field, our chapter was not written withany pretension to invent a ‘wheel’. The intent isthat it would serve to raise political awarenessand communicate a set of selected policy options<strong>for</strong> decision makers in <strong>the</strong> hope of improving substantiallyequitable property rights protection <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor and societies at large. The general treatmentof such a sensitive and context-dependentissue implies an inevitable trade-off between simplicityand comprehensiveness.It should be noted at <strong>the</strong> outset that <strong>the</strong> chair,rapporteur and contributors to this chapter(named at <strong>the</strong> beginning of this volume) have all74


contributed to its substance. But as drafted andsyn<strong>the</strong>sised by <strong>the</strong> rapporteur, <strong>the</strong> content mightnot always represent all <strong>the</strong> viewpoints and priorities.Positions taken should thus not be directlyattributed to all contributors — some positions,in fact, remain controversial among <strong>the</strong>m. Thereare two general points in relation to which <strong>the</strong>contributors voiced conflicting views to <strong>the</strong> rapporteur:<strong>the</strong> first concerns <strong>the</strong> role of <strong>the</strong> state;<strong>the</strong> second, <strong>the</strong> role of <strong>the</strong> market. While somesee <strong>the</strong> state as an indispensable part of <strong>the</strong> solutionto <strong>the</strong> problem of faltering property rights<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor, o<strong>the</strong>rs emphasise that it is ra<strong>the</strong>rpart of <strong>the</strong> problem or even <strong>the</strong> root cause. And,while some see <strong>the</strong> market as an opportunity <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor to w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>the</strong>mselves out of poverty, o<strong>the</strong>rsstress <strong>the</strong> fact that market <strong>for</strong>ces marginalize <strong>the</strong>poor and drive <strong>the</strong>m into misery.Acloser look reveals that <strong>the</strong>se diagnosticview points are often context-dependent. Torealise property rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor, both <strong>the</strong> stateas enabler and lender of last resort in regulationand rule implementation, as well as <strong>the</strong> marketas prime producer of resources, need close attention.Both state and market have indeed beenneglecting or harming <strong>the</strong> poor, but in <strong>the</strong> fightagainst poverty <strong>the</strong>re is no alternative to <strong>the</strong>dynamic relation between a re<strong>for</strong>med and morelegitimate state and a functional market that includes<strong>the</strong> poor in <strong>the</strong> value chains. This chapter<strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e stresses <strong>the</strong> dynamic interdependenceof state and market and <strong>the</strong> equal importanceof <strong>the</strong>ir re<strong>for</strong>m in <strong>the</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>ts to empower <strong>the</strong>poor through property rights. There is consensusamong <strong>the</strong> members of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing group whichprepared this chapter that <strong>the</strong> state as suchshould not be <strong>the</strong> default owner of land propertyand natural resources. The state is, however, indispensableas regulator, enabler, and auctioneerof equitable property relations. Increasing <strong>the</strong>legitimacy of <strong>the</strong> state thus belongs at <strong>the</strong> centreof <strong>the</strong> national and multilateral agenda of propertyrights protection.Realisation of property rights is about creating apositive feedback loop between <strong>the</strong> functionalityof property governance by <strong>the</strong> state on <strong>the</strong> oneside, and <strong>the</strong> meaning this systemic functionalityhas <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> people in <strong>the</strong>ir everyday life and customs.Importantly, nei<strong>the</strong>r of <strong>the</strong>se two elementsis to be understood as rigid and unchangeable. 34Culture and customs are subject to constantchange due to urbanisation, population growth,migration, social differentiation, technologicaldevelopment, etc., and so are <strong>the</strong> state’s institutionalrules and <strong>for</strong>mal procedures. If propertyrights are to bring substantial benefits to <strong>the</strong> globalpoor, <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>malised property systems of poorcountries and <strong>the</strong> social practices have to evolvetoge<strong>the</strong>r and in response to each o<strong>the</strong>r.75


2. Faltering Property Rights:<strong>the</strong> Nature and Scale of <strong>the</strong>ProblemAbsence, unjust allocation, or insecurity of propertyrights harm <strong>the</strong> poor and hinder sustainabledevelopment of a society. 35 Faltering propertyrights protection is related to <strong>the</strong> disenfranchisementof billions of poor people. In many cases,<strong>the</strong> inappropriate property rights system is <strong>the</strong>immediate cause of continued social, economic,and political disenfranchisement. This sectionwill highlight <strong>the</strong> most critical areas as well as<strong>the</strong> most vulnerable groups of people affected by<strong>the</strong> dire consequences of <strong>the</strong> absence or dysfunctionof property rights protection.Growing Slums and Legal VoidsAt least a third of <strong>the</strong> world’s poor live in irregularsettlements without coherent legal protectionof <strong>the</strong>ir assets. Population and urban settlementgrowth projections predict an aggravation of <strong>the</strong>problem. The UN Human Settlements Programmeholds that over <strong>the</strong> next 25 years more than 2billion urban dwellers could be added to <strong>the</strong> closeto 1 billion now living in slums, with some 2.825billion requiring housing and urban services by2030. If no action is taken most of this growthwill occur outside <strong>the</strong> legally protected sector. 37The consequences of <strong>the</strong> exclusion of <strong>the</strong> poor asa result of rapid urbanisation and modernisationare being acutely manifested around <strong>the</strong> world. In<strong>the</strong> final analysis, among all <strong>the</strong> causal factors <strong>for</strong>displacement, first and <strong>for</strong>emost is lack of securityof tenure <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor, who have no en<strong>for</strong>ceableproperty rights or access to justice.Box 1 The world’s poor:a demographic noteGlobally 53 percent of <strong>the</strong> population is defined aspoor by <strong>the</strong> ‘living under US$2 a day standard’ or3.4 billion people. The poor live in mainly six regionsand particularly three: South Central Asia (whichincludes populous India), <strong>the</strong> even more populousChina, and Sub-Saharan Africa. They represent <strong>the</strong>majority in South Central Asia (75 %) and Sub-SaharanAfrica (75 %) and just under half of all Chinese(47 %). Toge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> poor in <strong>the</strong>se three zonescomprise 70 percent of <strong>the</strong> global poor. 36Dire Consequences and Missed DevelopmentOpportunitiesWithout en<strong>for</strong>ceable property rights, residents ofin<strong>for</strong>mal settlements are often subject to <strong>for</strong>cefuleviction. They must fend <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>mselves or paybribes to local landlords to defend <strong>the</strong>ir right tooccupy land, protect it from harmful encroachment,and settle disputes. Lack of protection,of tenure and of legal leverage <strong>for</strong> economicactivity, decreases productivity. It leads to socialexclusion, reproduced over generations and visiblein <strong>the</strong> spatial segregation of <strong>the</strong> poor in <strong>the</strong>urban housing environment. Environmental andbehavioural degradation is closely linked to <strong>the</strong>vicious circles perpetuated by faltering propertyrights systems which fail <strong>the</strong> poor and slow down<strong>the</strong> development of society at large. Residents inextra-legal settlements have no legitimate way totransfer a home to a family member or heir nor torent or sell to ano<strong>the</strong>r. Illegal black land marketsemerge and abusive practices become prevalent.Due to a lack of property rights guarantee, manyassets in developing nations are not fungible. Thepoor and <strong>the</strong>ir potential business partners haveno criteria to establish or realise <strong>the</strong> potential of<strong>the</strong>ir assets. There is no clear reciprocity <strong>for</strong> holdingeach o<strong>the</strong>r accountable and no sufficient ba-76


sis to protect transactions or to pool assets witho<strong>the</strong>rs. For <strong>the</strong> national economy, extra-legalitysets off a cycle of disinvestment in housing; itrepresents a lost opportunity to stimulate productiveeconomic activity.Rural Poverty and Property RightsDespite continuing urbanisation, two-thirdsof <strong>the</strong> poor live in rural areas. Ninety-fivepercent live in China, South Central Asia and SubSaharan Africa. Toge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>se rural poor account<strong>for</strong> around half <strong>the</strong> world’s total poor.Rural Land Relations and Extreme PovertyInsufficient land to live on, and insecure accessor rights over land, are well recognised factors insustaining poverty. 38 Rural landlessness is often<strong>the</strong> best predictor of extreme poverty and hunger.Inadequate rights regarding land often result inentrenched poverty and are significant impedimentsto rural development and to alleviation ofhunger. 39 Elimination of <strong>the</strong> causes of tenure insecurityis thus imperative <strong>for</strong> fighting poverty.Rural Land Relations and Armed Confl ictConflict over rural land ownership and accessis almost always near <strong>the</strong> centre of armed civilconflict. 40 With various degrees of prominence,war over land access has been a driver, such asbetween <strong>the</strong> land rights of farmers and pastoralists(Burkina Faso), citizens and strangers (Côted’Ivoire), indigenous and proto-colonial groups(Namibia, Liberia, Mozambique), and ethnicgroups (Rwanda, Burundi, Sudan, Uganda). Essentially,it is about conflicts of interest — andlegal rights — between <strong>the</strong> rural rich and ruralpoor. Not surprisingly, attention to <strong>the</strong> legalrights of <strong>the</strong> majority of poor is often an earlyplat<strong>for</strong>m of post-conflict re<strong>for</strong>ms, most recentlyin Sudan and Liberia, 41 quite aside from <strong>the</strong>need to address conflict-induced land losses andoccupations. 42Natural ResourcesLand is not <strong>the</strong> only aspect of rural property disorder.The majority of rural poor depend upon<strong>for</strong>ests, pastures and swamplands. Forests aloneaccount <strong>for</strong> 3.8 billion hectares, of which onebillion grow in Asia and Africa, <strong>the</strong> two poorestregions. 43 Issues of who legally owns <strong>the</strong>seresources, <strong>the</strong> land on which <strong>the</strong>y grow, and towhom <strong>the</strong> rental (concession) and product valuesaccrue is an urgent concern of <strong>the</strong> rural poor. 44As <strong>the</strong> tenure and benefit share of <strong>for</strong>eshore andseedbed resources, fish-rich swamplands and(especially near-surface) minerals all deliver millionsof dollars annually to non-customary ownersand, notably, to governments, <strong>the</strong>re are ownershipissues to be considered.The importance of water rights and <strong>the</strong>ir relationto land rights is likely to increase. Already today,close to one third of <strong>the</strong> world’s population sufferfrom moderate to high water shortage. The WorldCommission on Water estimates that <strong>the</strong> demand<strong>for</strong> water will increase by around 50 percent in<strong>the</strong> next 30 years and that around 4 billion peoplewill live in severe conditions of water shortage by2025. 45 Increased pressure on water resources isa result of population increase as well as economicgrowth. The value of land and real property oftendepends directly on <strong>the</strong> existence of adequate waterrights. In this situation property rights definingwho has access to water will play a key role. Decisionsabout water rights will become increasinglyimportant with direct impact on rights and opportunitiesconcerning <strong>the</strong> use of land. 46Women Especially AffectedWomen own less than 10 percent of <strong>the</strong> world’sproperty: 47 They constitute half <strong>the</strong> world’s popu-77


Table 2 The rural poor in <strong>the</strong> poorest regions of <strong>the</strong> world(Population figures in millions)Poorest Regionsof <strong>the</strong> World**TotalPopulation2005Percentdefinedas poor*Number ofpoor 2005Percent inrural areasEst. number ofrural poorSub Saharan Africa 752 75 564 66 372South Central Asia 1615 75 1211 70 848China 1304 47 613 63 386North Africa 194 29 56 53 30Latin America and Caribbean 559 26 145 24 35Eastern Europe 297 14 42 32 134,721 56 2,631 64 1,684* Excludes Europe, Oceania, North America, etc.** The Population Reference Bureau uses <strong>the</strong> internationally-recognised criterion of living on less than $2 a day as <strong>the</strong> measure of poverty.lation, <strong>the</strong>y produce between 60 and 80 percentof <strong>the</strong> food in developing countries, and <strong>the</strong>y areresponsible <strong>for</strong> rural households in increasingnumbers. Much of <strong>the</strong> misery in <strong>the</strong> developingworld is due to statutory and customary propertysystems which disenfranchise women. 48 Wherewomen have property rights, <strong>the</strong>y often comein ‘thin bundles’ as compared with men. 49 Toofrequently women face barriers to owning, using,and transferring or inheriting property. Womenface <strong>for</strong>cible eviction from <strong>the</strong>ir homes and <strong>the</strong>irland (over which <strong>the</strong>y had customary or o<strong>the</strong>rrights) by family members, traditional authoritiesand/or neighbours. 50 Property grabbing exacerbatesurbanisation trends, sending more womento in<strong>for</strong>mal settlements and slums from urbanareas. The problem is intertwined with that ofinheritance, as many widows are evicted fromland and property. Barriers exist de jure if statutesor regulations prohibit women from using,owing, or inheriting property. Enacting <strong>for</strong>mallaws that provide a woman with property rightsdoes not necessarily mean that she will be able toexercise her rights. Often, barriers to <strong>the</strong> exerciseof property rights are found to exist de facto, inconsequence of poor en<strong>for</strong>cement of <strong>for</strong>mal rightsor of social norms.Creating en<strong>for</strong>ceable property rights is essentialto empower women in both ruraland urban settings. 51 Women who own propertyor o<strong>the</strong>rwise control assets directly gain fromsuch benefits as use of <strong>the</strong> land and higher incomesas well as having a secure place to live. 52Empowering women with property rights does agreat deal to alleviate poverty and malnutrition,as women who earn more spend a higher proportionof <strong>the</strong>ir income to keep <strong>the</strong>ir children healthyand well-fed. 53 Providing women with <strong>the</strong> right touse, own, and transfer moveable and immovableproperty is important to promote entrepreneurialactivity and to provide women with a plat<strong>for</strong>m <strong>for</strong>building strong families and strong businesses.Indigenous PeoplesDefinition of Indigenous Peoples Has Yet to ReachSatisfactory Maturation: Indigenous peoplesdistinguish <strong>the</strong>mselves by being historically, socially,economically, institutionally and politicallymarginalized. That <strong>the</strong>y are usually 54 a minority78


in <strong>the</strong>ir countries is added reason to take specialsteps to ensure that <strong>the</strong>ir interests are not ignored.Indigenous peoples are generally described asnumbering around 300-370 million people withinup to 5,000 distinctive groups. In June 2006, <strong>the</strong>UN Human Rights Council adopted The Declarationon <strong>the</strong> Rights of Indigenous Peoples, draftingof which had begun in <strong>the</strong> 1980s. The definitionof indigenous peoples has seen repeated amendment55 and remains contested, particularly on <strong>the</strong>African continent. This was a factor in <strong>the</strong> failureof <strong>the</strong> Declaration to meet UN General Assemblyapproval in November 2006.Focus on Indigenous Tenure SystemsMany indigenous lands have been and still aredeclared public or unoccupied because <strong>the</strong>y areheld collectively according to conceptions ofownership and access that do not fit well withimported property systems. This lack of statushas consequences <strong>for</strong> indigenous asset holdersand society at large and is a critical issue, globally,<strong>for</strong> property rights re<strong>for</strong>m. In addressingproblems of land issues of indigenous peoplesaround <strong>the</strong> world, it is advantageous to focusupon indigenous land tenure systems ra<strong>the</strong>r thanon <strong>the</strong> identification of indigenous people per se.This sidesteps <strong>the</strong> troubled definition as to whois and who is not ‘indigenous’ and has <strong>the</strong> addedadvantage of zeroing in on <strong>the</strong> systemic issues ofindigenous or customary tenure regimes.Where ethnic and indigenous minorities areidentified and territorially placed, it maybe unnecessary to belabour distinctions between<strong>the</strong> indigenous and <strong>the</strong>ir tenure systems. In suchcases, it is advisable to simply promote <strong>the</strong>irterritorial autonomy and sovereignty. It shouldinclude <strong>the</strong>ir stewardship over natural resources,and extend to matters of property — and all withoutside intervention kept to a minimum. Focus onindigenous or customary tenure systems is criticalin <strong>the</strong> two regions where <strong>the</strong> poor are most numerous— Sub-Saharan Africa and Central Asia— and where delimitation and identification ofindigenous peoples is difficult and contested.Important Numbers of Customary Land HoldersCustomary land holders comprise roughly two billionpeople in Africa, South East and South CentralAsia and Latin America and <strong>the</strong> Caribbean.Given that around 80 percent of <strong>the</strong>se rural dwellersare defined as ‘poor’ — i.e., living onTable 3 Main Regions Where Customary Land Tenure Operates(Population figures are in millions)RegionsPopulation2005percentRuralNumberRuralpercentdefinedas poor*Numberof poor2005Number ofrural poorSub Saharan Africa 752 66 496 75 564 372North Africa 194 53 103 29 56 30South Central Asia 1615 70 1130 75 1211 848South East Asia 557 62 345 56 312 345Latin America and Caribbean 559 24 134 26 145 353,677 60 2,208 71 2,288 1,630Source of base fi gures: Population Census Bureau, 2005. 5679


under US$2 a day standard — <strong>the</strong>n 1.6 billionpeople may be defined as ‘<strong>the</strong> customary poor’.Refugees, Internally DisplacedPersonsThe disorder of property relations created byinternal or interstate conflict deserves specialattention. 57 Putting property relations backin order or providing adequate compensation tovictims is at <strong>the</strong> heart of sustainable peace building.58 The situation becomes more dramatic whennatural disasters strike. In recent memory, <strong>the</strong>numbers displaced by <strong>the</strong> three major disasterssince <strong>the</strong> end of 2004 (<strong>the</strong> tsunamis of 26 December2004, Hurricane Katrina of 29 August2005, and <strong>the</strong> earthquake of 8 October 2005 innor<strong>the</strong>rn Pakistan and adjoining areas in Indiaand Afghanistan), is around 2 million, accordingto <strong>the</strong> Representative of <strong>the</strong> UN Secretary-Generalon <strong>the</strong> human rights of internally displacedpersons. 59 Given <strong>the</strong> fact of global warming, and<strong>the</strong> increasing number of natural disasters, <strong>the</strong>number of displaced persons falling into uncertainproperty relations is likely to grow. Also,empowerment of <strong>the</strong> poor through property rightshas to be seen as most urgent <strong>for</strong> orderly reestablishmentof property relations after disastersand <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> development of reliable insuranceschemes. 60 Hurricane Katrina victims had propertyrights and insurance schemes that mitigated<strong>the</strong>ir losses. The poorest people of <strong>the</strong> world lackand desperately need such securities.3. Barriers versusFacilitators of ChangeThere is evidence of enormous social and economicpotential in <strong>the</strong> establishment of propertyrights systems <strong>for</strong> all societies. 61 This insightleads to <strong>the</strong> question as to what actors and structuralbarriers prevent societies from adopting generallybeneficial property rights systems and whatcan be done to overcome <strong>the</strong>se barriers.Resistance of Powerful SocialActorsPrivate owners of illegally occupied propertyoften resist allocating land to squatters againstmarket value compensation. 62 Some businessactors profiting from monopoly-like positions wantto avoid competition. They resist legalisationand undermine good governance. 63 <strong>Law</strong>yers andnotaries profit from <strong>the</strong> complexity of legal propertysystems excluding <strong>the</strong> poor. 64 State officialsprofit from bureaucratic complexity of <strong>the</strong> systemthrough gatekeeping and briberies. Entrepreneursin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector refrain from registeringbusinesses and property to avoid taxes and costlyregulations. 65Structural Obstacles andFacilitators of ChangeActors tackling <strong>the</strong> task of re<strong>for</strong>m also have tobe aware of structural causes of stagnation orchange. The distribution of power plays an importantrole in determining <strong>the</strong> likelihood of <strong>the</strong>emergence of fair property rights systems. Landand income distribution is ano<strong>the</strong>r factor in thisregard. Indeed, it has been shown that <strong>the</strong> natureof <strong>the</strong> prevailing political regime and land andincome inequality are important determinants ofproperty rights structure. 66 When political power80


is concentrated in <strong>the</strong> hands of <strong>the</strong> few, and/orland and income distribution is skewed resultingin extreme inequality, political authorities areunlikely to implement and en<strong>for</strong>ce property rightsin an equitable manner. 67 This indicates that <strong>the</strong>evolution of property rights systems is to a largeextent determined by historical conditions, suchas <strong>the</strong> distribution of factors of production. 68Realising TurnaroundUnderstanding <strong>the</strong> likely impact of re<strong>for</strong>ms onnon-poor groups with significant influenceis critical to assess potential support and opposition<strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms. 69 Besides promoting pro-poorproperty rights it is <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e important to establishproperty rights systems that are beneficial<strong>for</strong> middle classes and groups with significantassets and political influence. The message to allis that in <strong>the</strong> absence of generalised and equitableproperty rights systems much of economicactivity does not develop its full potential even<strong>for</strong> powerful actors 70 ; <strong>the</strong>re is a high likelihood ofsocial unrest 71 ; <strong>the</strong>re may be under-accumulationof human capital resulting in a low quality labour<strong>for</strong>ce, and little demand <strong>for</strong> credit resulting in underdevelopedfinancial institutions and ultimatelyhindered growth. There is also less <strong>for</strong>eign investmentor flight of capital when property rights arenot guaranteed.scenario. The emergence of property rights and<strong>the</strong> distribution of resources may have mutualcausal effect. 73 Examples of countries like Chinaand Singapore teach us that an alternative routeof political authorities consenting to re<strong>for</strong>ms isa possibility where inequalities are less extreme.The issue of better understanding how to devisemechanisms <strong>for</strong> convincing <strong>the</strong> political authoritiesor circumventing <strong>the</strong>ir influence in orderto induce <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m constitutes an importantchallenge. An important implication of this viewis that a drastic one-time re<strong>for</strong>m may have longlasting consequences, setting <strong>the</strong> process of everimproving distribution along side with more equitableproperty rights systems.Provided that inequalities are not too extreme,equitable property rights may emerge preciselybecause of <strong>the</strong>ir beneficial consequences <strong>for</strong>groups with significant assets and political influence.They may also emerge out of <strong>the</strong> desireof elites to avoid adverse consequences fromexceeding numbers of poor people not havingaccess to property rights. 72 Indeed, several recentexamples in Asia, where political leadersinduced progressive re<strong>for</strong>ms, including equitableproperty rights, are illustrative of precisely this81


4. Learning from <strong>the</strong> PastLearning from previous re<strong>for</strong>ms in view of improvingpractices carries considerable burdens of judgmentas one tries to measure <strong>the</strong> possible applicabilityof particular lessons to future re<strong>for</strong>ms in very differentcontexts. What is provided in this section isa compressed selection of lessons to give actors on<strong>the</strong> ground better conditions to reach <strong>the</strong>ir own in<strong>for</strong>medjudgment.Problematic Practices and OmissionsSix general lessons from past mistakes arepresented as follows:1) Disregarding that effective property rights <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor are <strong>the</strong> result of power relations andsystemic interaction. Many ef<strong>for</strong>ts to give <strong>the</strong>poor effective and en<strong>for</strong>ceable property rightshave focused on necessary technical and legalissues at <strong>the</strong> expense of paying attentionto how power relations influence <strong>the</strong> propertyrights system in its impact on <strong>the</strong> most vulnerablemembers of society. This has hinderedeffective realisation of <strong>the</strong>oretically anticipatedre<strong>for</strong>m benefits <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor. Associationalpower of <strong>the</strong> poor, more symmetric in<strong>for</strong>mation,legal literacy, procedural assistance andinstitutional capacity building are as importantas <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal legal instruments of propertyrights. 742) Failing to assess <strong>the</strong> credit market environmentof <strong>the</strong> property system and assumingthat credit markets will evolve automaticallyfrom property rights. In general, rates of mortgagingremain very low in developing countries,partly due to low demand, partly due toavailability of less risky alternative sources ofloans than possible <strong>for</strong>eclosure threatens andin <strong>the</strong> past partly due to low values in a market.75 Given <strong>the</strong> reluctance of banks to destroy<strong>the</strong> entire livelihood of a poor family in <strong>the</strong>event of <strong>for</strong>eclosure and <strong>the</strong> likelihood of localresistance to attempts to take or sell off <strong>the</strong>collateralised property, <strong>the</strong>re is limited accessto mortgages and credit, especially in ruralareas. 76 Understanding <strong>the</strong> role of credit marketsin relation to property rights <strong>for</strong>malisationhas led to some important shifts in donor landpolicies in recent years. It is now acceptedthat <strong>for</strong> markets to move land and real propertyto <strong>the</strong> poor in a sustainable manner targetedcredit must be provided.3) Assuming that <strong>the</strong> state is strong and trustworthyand that <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e property titles and registriesas well as <strong>the</strong> guarantee of transactionsare reliable and corruption proof. 77 In manycountries land administration is one of <strong>the</strong>most corrupt public services. The most egregiousexamples include irregularities and outrightfraud in allocating and managing publiclands. Even petty corruption in regular servicedelivery can involve large sums and have farreachingeconomic consequences. 784) Failure to include moveable property andshareholder schemes of ownership and valueaddition in policies promoting property rights.The asset base of <strong>the</strong> poor can be extended byinnovative <strong>for</strong>ms of non-real estate and noncreditbased corporate shareholder ownershipand by using moveable property as collateral.Unlike land and housing, <strong>the</strong> reproductivepotential of non-tangible <strong>for</strong>ms of property ispotentially unlimited.5) Repressing Opportunities alongside with Risk.Even a moderate increase in <strong>the</strong> liberties andentitlements that come with private property,be it owned by individuals or groups, can oftencreate considerable benefits. 79 Thin bundlesof property rights, reducing <strong>the</strong> fungibility of82


property, contribute to <strong>the</strong> exclusion of <strong>the</strong> poorfrom <strong>the</strong> chain of value addition in case of landdevelopment, compensation payments, andgeneral increase of property value. The risksof <strong>the</strong> land and financial market have invitedspecial policy measures which are supposedto protect <strong>the</strong> poor from predators and harmfulmarket <strong>for</strong>ces. Such practices mainly includeconditionality of <strong>for</strong>ming collectives in orderto register property under a single legal entity,restrictions on <strong>the</strong> right to transfer (moratoria)after land privatisation or titling, quantitativeceilings of ownership, special qualification toprofit from land and real estate redistribution.The incentives to <strong>for</strong>m collectives are beneficialwhere <strong>the</strong>y are related to and protectexisting communal structures. 80 They are oftendysfunctional in contexts where a majority or avery active minority of people wants to act asindividuals or small family groups and where<strong>the</strong> moratoria are too long and time is notused <strong>for</strong> capacity building. 816) Failure to conceive gender equitable propertyrights systems. In many countries, <strong>for</strong>malstatutory law operates in conjunction with customarylaw and cultural norms and practicesbased on patriarchal attitudes which makeit difficult to en<strong>for</strong>ce women’s legal rights toland as wives and daughters. Individualisticstatutory law favouring <strong>the</strong> male householdhead and customary practices and hierarchiescombine into a mix that is harmful <strong>for</strong> women.Where customary law and more gender consciencestatutory law conflict, oftentimes <strong>the</strong>customary law trumps. In some instancesstatutory law has erased customary practicesfavouring widows or women in general. Legalre<strong>for</strong>m does not improve <strong>the</strong> precarious propertyrights situation of women if <strong>the</strong>re are noen<strong>for</strong>cement mechanisms, and if legal assistanceand support services are not af<strong>for</strong>dableor accessible <strong>for</strong> women. 82Lessons from mistakes related to land and realproperty:1) Failure to address <strong>the</strong> problem of landlessnessand extremely unequal land distribution.Market based re<strong>for</strong>ms are not <strong>the</strong> definitesolution to this problem, but land purchaseand redistribution of underused land by <strong>the</strong>state, multilateral donors or land-banks byprivate foundations can avoid <strong>the</strong> social unrestand withdrawal of private investment usuallycaused by compulsory acquisition and expropriation.832) Retaining that customary tenure and interestsin commons does not represent private propertyrights in and of <strong>the</strong>mselves and are <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>enot eligible <strong>for</strong> registration without conversioninto imported <strong>for</strong>ms. 84 Sustaining versions ofcollective assets in particular as ‘un-ownedland’ or default state-owned, instead of registering<strong>the</strong>se as <strong>the</strong> private, group-owned propertyof communities has deprived millions of poorof a secure asset and income base. Customarytenure systems were thought to provide insufficienttenure security. They were assumed toimpede farmers from making necessary investmentsin land and <strong>the</strong>y were associated with<strong>the</strong> ‘tragedy of <strong>the</strong> commons.’ 85 Research hasshown that such systems can be effective. Bydefault and notwithstanding important qualifications,customary tenure systems are to beconsidered as providing an adequate framew<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong> private group-owned property. They havebeen flexible and responsive to changing economiccircumstances. 86 They limit <strong>the</strong> propertyrights bundle to a specific group of people as<strong>the</strong> bearers of those rights. The household, <strong>the</strong>village, and <strong>the</strong> kin group often provide insur-83


ance against risks, access to in<strong>for</strong>mal credit,and security. Lineage rules of inheritance helpen<strong>for</strong>ce intergenerational transfers. The threatof social exclusion is a major instrument ofen<strong>for</strong>cement of <strong>the</strong> rules. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, essentialfunctions of <strong>the</strong> property rights systemare fulfilled by customary systems and ought tobe legally rein<strong>for</strong>ced. 873) Assuming high demand <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal entitlement,i.e. assuming that rural and remote landholdersfelt <strong>the</strong>ir rights to <strong>the</strong>ir house and farmplots are threatened or that <strong>the</strong>y explicitlywant to raise loans on <strong>the</strong> basis of <strong>for</strong>mal titlesto <strong>the</strong>se assets. 88 Paying insufficient attentionto <strong>the</strong> time and financial costs of titling,to both government and landholder. 89 In particularassuming that titling always has to becadastre-based and rest upon expensive surveyand mapping. 904) Assuming that titling is <strong>the</strong> precondition <strong>for</strong>property security when o<strong>the</strong>r measures offermore immediate and simpler ways of securing<strong>the</strong> assets of <strong>the</strong> poor, especially in remote ruralareas. Even in rural African contexts, whereindividual titling of land may not be desirableor feasible and <strong>the</strong> use of land as collateral <strong>for</strong>credit is only a remote possibility, providingpoor land owners or users with documentedrights can yield significant benefits. 915) Failing to pay attention to pro-poor land marketdevelopment and failing to assess <strong>the</strong> impactof <strong>the</strong> land market on <strong>the</strong> poor. 926) Failure to Simplify Land Administration <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> Least Advantaged Customer. In manycountries, land administration functions aredispersed among many Ministries (justice,environment, agriculture, urban, finance, landre<strong>for</strong>m, <strong>for</strong>est, mining, etc.). This createsgrey zones of overlapping competencies as abreeding ground <strong>for</strong> non-transparent practices.Even if responsibilities are clearly assignedand overlaps avoided, this creates confusionamong users, prevents realisation of economiesof scale, and thus increases <strong>the</strong> cost ofproviding land administration services to <strong>the</strong>detriment of <strong>the</strong> poor. 937) Failing to Restrict Eminent Domain. Thereshould be a strict focus on using eminentdomain as ultima ratio in providing essentialpublic services ra<strong>the</strong>r than as a means toimprove general public utility. The latter promotesillegitimate alliances of state ownershipand powerful particular interest and severelydamages <strong>the</strong> property rights of marginal landusers by excluding <strong>the</strong>m from adequate compensationor inclusion in chains of value additionthrough property development.8) Insufficient Revenue Sharing in Gains fromNatural Resources. There has been lack of attentionto <strong>the</strong> possibility of community basednatural resource management in <strong>the</strong> case of<strong>for</strong>ests, fishery, and water. There has beeninsufficient participation of citizens in <strong>the</strong>revenues from <strong>the</strong> extraction, treatment, anddistribution of natural resources.Experienced Consequences1) Enduring extra-legality of <strong>the</strong> majority of assetholders despite existing property systems andtitling programmes is a persisting phenomenon.It is due to imperfect implementationin some cases but in many o<strong>the</strong>r settings it is<strong>the</strong> result of a mismatch of official institutionsand local practices.2) Disruption of Existing Tenurial Arrangements.Careless implementation of <strong>for</strong>mal documentationmay have <strong>the</strong> effect of inadvertentlydisrupting existing tenurial arrangements.84


There may be sound policy reasons <strong>for</strong> seekingto modify or eliminate some existing tenurialpractices. It is important, however, that anysuch re<strong>for</strong>ms are <strong>the</strong> result of in<strong>for</strong>med andparticipatory decision-making, and not <strong>the</strong>inadvertent result of poorly designed or implementedtitling processes.3) Concentration and Discrimination. In manycountries, including <strong>the</strong> countries of <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>merSoviet Union, it has been observed that somepeople may be less well positioned to participateeffectively in <strong>the</strong> documentation and registrationprocess than o<strong>the</strong>rs, with <strong>the</strong> effect that<strong>the</strong>ir rights are poorly protected. Individualswho loose in such contexts are usually women,absentee right holders or mortgagees, and ingeneral people with less education and limitedaccess to in<strong>for</strong>mation becoming victim to manipulationand fraud.4) Increase in Disputes. Registration of landis expected to reduce <strong>the</strong> incidence of landdisputes, by clarifying boundaries, by resolvingambiguities about rights over land and byputting in place a registration system that istransparent, reliable and accessible. In <strong>the</strong>short term, however, <strong>the</strong> process of adjudicationand <strong>for</strong>malisation of rights may bringto <strong>the</strong> surface latent disputes that may haveo<strong>the</strong>rwise remained below <strong>the</strong> surface. Suchpotential risk needs to be assessed in <strong>the</strong>planning phase of a re<strong>for</strong>m project.5) Capitalisation: Difficult <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor in Absenceof Adequate Land and Capital Markets.State of <strong>the</strong> art analysis reveals only a modestpositive effect of land titling on access tomortgage credit, and no impact on access too<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>ms of credit. It shows no effect on <strong>the</strong>labour income of <strong>the</strong> households holding newtitles. However, it is shown that moving a poorhousehold from uncertain usufructuary rightsto a more complete bundle of property rightssubstantially increased investment in <strong>the</strong> familyhouses. Property registration and guaranteeof <strong>the</strong> homes reduced <strong>the</strong> size of families and<strong>the</strong>se smaller families invested more in <strong>the</strong>education of <strong>the</strong>ir children. Ano<strong>the</strong>r study findsthat <strong>for</strong>mal property rights lead to more availabletime <strong>for</strong> productive activities of propertyholders who do no longer need to defend <strong>the</strong>irassets. 94Property rights bring increased economic benefitswhen linked to a functional credit systemand market, but <strong>the</strong>y do not, by <strong>the</strong>mselves,cause <strong>the</strong> emergence of a functional and propoorcredit system. 95 Legal property rights effectivelylead to credit and investment whererobust financial markets exist and where <strong>the</strong>reare fur<strong>the</strong>r incentives <strong>for</strong> investment. 96 Evenwhen in possession of titles and registeredproperty, small-scale farmers and <strong>the</strong> urbanpoor most often do not put <strong>the</strong>ir land or modestdwellings at risk by using <strong>the</strong>m as collateral<strong>for</strong> credit. 97 Tenure security and economicbenefits o<strong>the</strong>r than capitalisation via collateralof land property seem to be primordial <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor. Although <strong>the</strong>y are efficient producers,small-scale farmers and business peopletend to lose out in land and financial marketswhich are regulated with provisions that privilegeconsolidation. Market based land re<strong>for</strong>ms<strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e now tend to be accompanied withtargeted credit <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor.6) Costs and Benefits of Property Rights Protection.From <strong>the</strong> perspective of <strong>the</strong> poor and<strong>the</strong> state, <strong>the</strong> costs of <strong>for</strong>mal titles have tobe weighed against <strong>the</strong> costs of insecurity oftenure, or against in<strong>for</strong>mal costs (bribes) inobtaining titles which harm <strong>the</strong> poor and <strong>the</strong>state. 98 In many unre<strong>for</strong>med contexts, only few85


households can af<strong>for</strong>d <strong>the</strong> cost of a title. 99 Aswill be discussed, adapting laws and proceduresto <strong>the</strong> social context can considerablyreduce <strong>the</strong> costs of titling and registrationby reducing administrative inefficiencies andby <strong>the</strong> use of modern technology. Legally en<strong>for</strong>cedproperty rights systems are not necessarilycost ineffective and expensive. 1007) Fees and Taxes. The integration of irregularsettlements into legal property rights systemsincreases tax revenues to governments. 101 On<strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand it is obvious that inappropriatefees and taxes can push people back into extralegality.102 As far as <strong>the</strong> poor are concerned,registration fees and taxes have to be set atminimal levels. The key elements that have tobe in place <strong>for</strong> property tax re<strong>for</strong>m: existence ofadequate technical expertise; appropriate landrecords and administration are required as <strong>the</strong>basis <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> property lists; sufficient flexibilityto allow <strong>the</strong> phasing in of major changes is essentialto <strong>for</strong>estall challenges and resistance tochanges; political understanding and will areperhaps <strong>the</strong> most critical preconditions if <strong>the</strong>substantial challenges of implementing a highlyvisible, difficult to evade, tax, are to be overcome.1035. Recommendations <strong>for</strong>Re<strong>for</strong>m and ImprovedActionThe diversity of contexts and stakeholders affectedby problems of faltering property rights,as well as <strong>the</strong> high complexity of <strong>the</strong> issue, doesnot indicate that <strong>the</strong>re will be a one time, onesize-fits-allsolution. What is needed is a seriousand continuously monitored re<strong>for</strong>m process andparallel interventions inducing far-reaching andsustainable re<strong>for</strong>ms of <strong>the</strong> four building blocks of<strong>the</strong> property rights system; that is: (1) re<strong>for</strong>ming<strong>the</strong> property system as one of rules defining orenabling bundles and bearers of property rightsallowing <strong>the</strong> poor to access and secure propertyalone, as members of communities, or as communities;(2) re<strong>for</strong>ming it as a system of governanceso that targeted actions securing <strong>the</strong> propertyrights of <strong>the</strong> poor can be taken effectively and legitimately;(3) re<strong>for</strong>ming it as a functioning marketof assets to include <strong>the</strong> poor in <strong>the</strong> chains ofvalue addition enabling <strong>the</strong>m to become capablemarket participants, and (4) re<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>the</strong> propertysystem as one of social policy with targetedmeasures of capacity building, in<strong>for</strong>mation, andaccess to property and housing. Parallel re<strong>for</strong>mw<strong>ork</strong> sustained by constant monitoring in all fourdimensions is advocated to achieve real progress.Common features of policy design and prioritisingare also dealt with in this section, and outlinesare presented of important subsidiary and stabilisingactions that ei<strong>the</strong>r have or can be taken bydonor countries and multilateral organisations.86Re<strong>for</strong>ming Rules Regarding Bearersand Bundles of Property RightsProperty rights stand <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> bundle of libertiesand claim rights tied to <strong>the</strong> allocation of a resourceto a natural or legal person. The property


system as a system of rules regarding <strong>the</strong> bundlesand bearers of property rights determineswho can legally own property, what is recognisedas property and what can be done with property.<strong>Law</strong>s should promote ra<strong>the</strong>r than limit ordiscriminate against bearers of property rights;<strong>the</strong>y should allow freedom to bestow sufficientlythick bundles of property rights on individuals orgroups and should not unduly limit <strong>the</strong> scope ofcreative activity that can be invested in property.Individual and common Private PropertyPromote Individual and Corporate Legal Identity;Limited Corporate Liability. Property law shouldoffer clear and simple options of legal personalityand corporate ownership <strong>for</strong> small businessesand corporative associations of <strong>the</strong> poor. Legalpersonality so designed opens a range of possibilitiesof ownership by individuals, membersof collectives, and by collectives. A legal personcan hold property as an individual, but <strong>the</strong> definitionof a legal person can also be extended toa collective or common property of a myriad ofmembers, who in turn may own some propertyrights individually. Pro-poor property rights systemsfacilitate <strong>the</strong> ability of people to pool andleverage modest resources and limit liabilities incase of business failure or exit of partners. Onekey to economic success <strong>for</strong> small entrepreneursin <strong>the</strong> developing world is <strong>the</strong> limited liability ofbusiness owners, allowing <strong>for</strong> controlled failurewithout disastrous consequences <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> vulnerableindividuals involved. This legal instrument oflimited corporate liability has to be extended to<strong>the</strong> poor micro entrepreneurs and rural producersin <strong>the</strong> developing world in a simple, straight<strong>for</strong>wardmanner. Its main advantage is <strong>for</strong>mality ofbusiness ownership that trumps disadvantages of<strong>for</strong>mality such as tariffs and taxes, provided <strong>the</strong>seare af<strong>for</strong>dable.Promote Associational Property Structures. Housingand land associations prove how individualand common property can be combined to favourpeople with limited assets without disenfranchising<strong>the</strong>m to a collectivity. The association, aslegal person, is owner of <strong>the</strong> real property andcollectively responsible <strong>for</strong> mortgage loans, giving<strong>the</strong> association more leverage in negotiatingloans and public services. Members, however, gettradable rights to plots, houses or apartments,and contribute to repayment of <strong>the</strong> overall loanthrough monthly rent. Apartments or plots areincreasingly sold at open market prices, but associationmembers have pre-emption rights toenter into <strong>the</strong> agreement at an agreed price. 104The idea is to provide a <strong>for</strong>m of ownership to balance<strong>the</strong> interests of <strong>the</strong> individual or family withthose of a broader community. With this purpose,Australia introduced Strata Title in 1961 to bettercope with apartment blocks. O<strong>the</strong>r countries haveadopted <strong>the</strong> Australian system of apartment ownership,including Canada, Singapore, Indonesia,Malaysia, Fiji and <strong>the</strong> Philippines, and still o<strong>the</strong>rshave successfully created <strong>the</strong>ir own schemes.Strata title is not only applicable to vertical livingbut also to cluster living in slums. In many developingcontexts, <strong>the</strong>re has been a tendency <strong>for</strong>law to prescribe in too much detail <strong>the</strong> structureof local organisations and <strong>the</strong> rules by which <strong>the</strong>ycan operate. At <strong>the</strong> same time, injecting greater<strong>for</strong>mality and accountability into local organisationsis obviously important.Simplified Property Rights Certification. Somecountries have adopted simple, locally administeredprocesses to confer legal land rights asalternatives to conventional land titling. They arepractical, inclusive, benefiting growing populationsof <strong>the</strong> rural poor, 105 and are being increasinglyused to enhance urban land tenure security.106 As many require no prior physical planning,87


Box 2 Acquiring property rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poorIn Pakistan, incremental expansion of urban servicesallowed conversion of in<strong>for</strong>mal settlements (katchiabadis) in Hyderabad into legal housing neighbourhoods.In Trinidad and Tobago <strong>the</strong>se alternativeinstruments have <strong>the</strong> advantage of being part of anincremental process of acquiring secure tenure. There,<strong>the</strong> State Land (Regularisation of Tenure) <strong>Law</strong> of 1998paved <strong>the</strong> way <strong>for</strong> progressive issue of Certificates ofCom<strong>for</strong>t, Statutory Leases and Deeds of Lease to in<strong>for</strong>malsettlers on state land. A similar model has beenunder development in Namibia since <strong>the</strong> late 1990sand proposes a continuum comprising Starter, Landholdand Freehold titles. In Brazil, <strong>the</strong> usucapião is a<strong>for</strong>m of adverse possession over private land, so <strong>the</strong>reis no need <strong>for</strong> authorities to issue a title: <strong>the</strong> judicialsentence declaring that a new real right over <strong>the</strong> landhas been constituted over time is <strong>the</strong> legal documentnecessary to promote land registration and ownershiptransfer. This can be done individually or collectively,and people get freehold rights ei<strong>the</strong>r individually orin a <strong>for</strong>m of co-ownership. It is a <strong>for</strong>m of prescriptiveacquisition, a real right (in <strong>the</strong> legal sense), and nottemporary. It can be sold, inherited, etc., and <strong>the</strong>re isno reason <strong>for</strong> banks not to accept it (Fernandes 2005).In India it is common practice to issue pattas givingrights to <strong>the</strong> poor over government land. The patta, adocument issued by <strong>the</strong> Land Revenue Department,may be freehold or leasehold (99/30/10/1yr), renewableor not. It specifies conditions <strong>for</strong> use, transfer andinheritance, and may be used to regularise occupationor assign new plots. The patta is usually given free ofcost, or with a small fee, and needs no registration toavail of rights specified. In states like Madhya Pradesh,Andhra Pradesh, Rajasthan and West Bengal, it canbe mortgaged against housing loans. If patta land isrequired <strong>for</strong> any ‘public purpose’, <strong>the</strong> holder has to beallotted alternate land. In Andhra Pradesh alone, morethan 10 million pattas have been issued since 1962.(Banerjee 2006)infrastructure, or surveying, <strong>the</strong>y offer widespreadcoverage at low cost, af<strong>for</strong>dable by <strong>the</strong> poor.Recognising Customary Tenure and Communitiesas Bearers of Property Rights to Land and NaturalResourcesIndividual titling and/or alternative measures <strong>for</strong>incremental consolidation of property claims areappropriate and beneficial in many urban contexts.107 In rural contexts, especially in Africa andparts of Asia, <strong>the</strong>y need to be phased in from o<strong>the</strong>r<strong>for</strong>ms of tenure security or replaced by new approachesto securing tenure to more fully cover <strong>the</strong>spectrum of <strong>the</strong> local economic practices and conditions.The 1990s and early 2000s are repletewith examples of legal re<strong>for</strong>ms in <strong>the</strong> direction ofrecognising customary land rights (mainly in Africa,and notably in Tanzania, Uganda, Mozambiqueand some West African countries), and indigenousland rights (Philippines, Cambodia, Australia, anda number of countries in Latin America). Theseinnovations come from different contexts that maylimit comparability; never<strong>the</strong>less, one can extractcommon threads and identify common problemsthat will require attention in <strong>the</strong> years ahead. 108Broadly speaking, <strong>the</strong>se laws share some of <strong>the</strong>following characteristics or aspirations:• They recognise that in many contexts <strong>the</strong>social and economic value of land is best realisedby allowing land relations to be governedby rules of <strong>the</strong> community in which <strong>the</strong> landis located, ra<strong>the</strong>r than by imposed systems ofproperty law.• They reflect a conviction that communitybasedtenure regimes are often better atproviding security of tenure to individual cultivators.Often, individual cultivators fear dis-88


Box 3 Namibian land re<strong>for</strong>mIn Namibia, legal re<strong>for</strong>ms in 1996 created a framew<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong> community-based natural resource management(CBNRM). Namibians who <strong>for</strong>m conservanciesnow have legal rights to manage wildlife andto benefit from tourism. With <strong>the</strong>se secured rights,rural Namibians have reduced levels of poaching,have seen wildlife numbers increase substantially,and are seeing <strong>the</strong>ir ecosystems rebounding. Arelated benefit is that rural Namibians now haveopportunities to pursue a new set of entrepreneurialventures. They are empowered to build businessesbased on eco-tourism and related activities. Thesebusinesses help to diversify livelihoods and providevaluable benefits <strong>for</strong> conservancy members.Namibia’s experience with CBNRM may provide astrong model <strong>for</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r countries: devolving securelegal rights to local people is promoting positiveoutcomes, both in terms of conservation and economicdevelopment. Source: Boudreaux 2007possession by government or outsiders, ra<strong>the</strong>rthan by o<strong>the</strong>rs within <strong>the</strong> community.• They acknowledge that community-basedsystems are also often better at reflecting <strong>the</strong>complex rights that individuals, families andgroups have over land, including secondaryrights of access and use — rights that mightbe distorted or lost by titling according to astandardise <strong>for</strong>mat that is not adapted to localrealities.• They recognise that a community’s relationshipwith land is more than an aggregate ofindividually occupied plots: it is a system thatincludes natural resources used in common.Communal lands and common natural resources.Including grazing lands, <strong>for</strong>ests, water, fisheries,in many poor countries are a special case of customarytenure and crucial <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> improvement of<strong>the</strong> legal and economic status of <strong>the</strong> poor. Theyare vulnerable to degradation and appropriationby powerful chiefs, outsiders, or state bureaucratsunless common property resource managementsystems are rein<strong>for</strong>ced by legal sanction.Increasing access to, and <strong>the</strong> locally beneficialproductivity of land and natural resources, can beachieved by:• Reaffirming and codifying customary rules inparticipatory ways, reflecting diversity in <strong>the</strong>ethnic, historical, and social construction ofland. Also setting legal boundaries, identifyingexisting rights that may overlap or be of a seasonalnature (e.g., between herders and sedentaryagriculturalists), and registering <strong>the</strong>mas appropriate and orderly tradable.• Allowing communal land ownership as onelegal option and regular management decisionsin an accountable body that functionstransparently — <strong>for</strong> example, as an incorporateduser group — and having clear rules <strong>for</strong>conflict resolution that are respected by allinvolved. Arriving at culturally appropriate legal<strong>for</strong>ms <strong>for</strong> such bodies is key.• Ensuring that customary <strong>for</strong>ms of tenure canevolve towards more <strong>for</strong>mal types of tenurethrough well-defined and transparent processes,if and when, in <strong>the</strong> judgment of thoseconcerned, <strong>the</strong> benefits from more individualownership exceed <strong>the</strong> cost. 109The status of in<strong>for</strong>mal rights has come strongly to<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>e. Most derive from, and are sustained by,community-based arrangements — i.e. indigenousor customary regimes. If inroads made thus farevolve and expand, some 400 million Africanscould benefit. No fewer than 40 million Indonesians,or 40 million South Americans — andmillions of o<strong>the</strong>rs globally — could also benefit,should comparable tentative shifts mature. The89


implications promise socio-economic changesnever quite achieved in previous re<strong>for</strong>ms towardsredistribution, collectivisation or conversionarytitling. Obviously, where states are too weak tocontrol local war and drug lords, devolving landownership or management to local communities isnot an option to empower <strong>the</strong> poor.Critical Issues in <strong>the</strong> Recognition of Customaryand Indigenous Tenure SystemsDrafting of laws that recognise customarytenure and that accommodate a numberof such tenure systems within a national legalframew<strong>ork</strong> is a complex task. It is possible toidentify a number of challenges that are likely torequire attention from both drafters and implementers:Identifying Communities and Evolving Practices.State recognition of customary or communitybasedtenure requires identifying, with some degreeof precision, <strong>the</strong> community whose propertyrights are being recognised, <strong>the</strong> area over whichit has legitimate claims and <strong>the</strong> institutions ordecision-making processes whose decisions andoutcomes are entitled to respect by <strong>for</strong>mal legalinstitutions. If carelessly done, <strong>for</strong>mal recognitionmay have <strong>the</strong> effect of unduly privileging one ofseveral competing local visions of what constitutesa community, and what rules or authoritiesare legitimate.Balancing Respect <strong>for</strong> Local Decision-makingwith Human Rights and Accountability. In somecontexts, custom may run contrary to a vision ofhuman rights enshrined in a national constitution,particularly where it comes to <strong>the</strong> treatmentof women and minorities. A similar dilemmaarises when it comes to ensuring minimum levelsof accountability and transparency within customarystructures. However, customs are not rigidand unchanging. It is thus possible to aim at aprocess in which customary practices evolve inresponse to social development and human rightsprinciples. 110Protecting Customary or Indigenous Rights whileEnhancing <strong>the</strong> Ability of Communities and IndividualHouseholds to Explore New EconomicOpportunities. There is no inherent contradictionbetween giving increased legal recognition to customaryor indigenous tenure systems and promotingeconomic growth — indeed, in some contextsit is argued that <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mer is a pre-requisite <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> latter. But <strong>the</strong> choice of legal techniques mayskew <strong>the</strong> balance between protection on <strong>the</strong> onehand and <strong>the</strong> ability to adapt to new opportunitiesor challenges on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r. Protecting <strong>the</strong>integrity of local systems against <strong>the</strong> incursions ofricher and more sophisticated outsiders may, asa starting point, justify short-term restrictions on<strong>the</strong> alienability of land. The question is whe<strong>the</strong>remphasis on protection reflects <strong>the</strong> needs and aspirationsof local people in rapidly changing economicenvironments. Some laws provide avenues<strong>for</strong> communities or individuals to attract outsideinvestment on <strong>the</strong>ir land, subject to an internalprocess of approval. There are in some cases opportunities<strong>for</strong> individuals or groups to ‘opt out’ oflocal tenure systems in favour of acquiring individualisedtitles under a state-sponsored scheme.The Challenge of Capacity and Conflict. Devolvinggreater authority to local institutions — whe<strong>the</strong>rtraditional bodies or local governments — has itsjustifications. The question to be asked in eachcase, however, is whe<strong>the</strong>r specific re<strong>for</strong>ms assume<strong>the</strong> existence of greater capacities at variouspoints in <strong>the</strong> system than in fact exist, or canbe expected to exist in <strong>the</strong> near future. In manycontexts, conflict-ridden areas will not allow<strong>for</strong> community based land and natural resourcemanagement and require tighter central control.The challenge of capacity and conflict extends90


Box 4 Focus AfricaCustomary rights may now be registered without conversioninto introduced <strong>for</strong>ms in Uganda, Tanzaniaand Mozambique; <strong>the</strong> same is proposed in Lesotho,Malawi and Madagascar. Customary properties o<strong>the</strong>rthan common properties may be registered in Namibiaand Botswana (since 1968). Although not defined ascustomary rights, given <strong>the</strong>ir abolition in 1975, existingoccupancy may also be registered ‘as is’ in Ethiopia.Customary rights in Mali, Niger, Burkina Faso, Benin,Côte d’Ivoire, Ghana and South Africa may be certificatedwith substantial effect, but with required or impliedconversion into existing statutory <strong>for</strong>ms on final registration.Described incidents of customary rights reflect‘customary freehold’ and/or as customarily agreed by<strong>the</strong> modern community. Most laws allow <strong>for</strong> customaryrights to be held in perpetuity, raising <strong>the</strong>ir statusabove that of leasehold or similar statutory <strong>for</strong>mscommon to most of Africa. Freehold is available mainlyin Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Africa. Only Tanzania and Mozambiqueendow customary interests with unequivocal equivalencywith imported tenure <strong>for</strong>ms. Uganda proclaimsthis but also provides <strong>for</strong> conversion of customary certificates into freehold tenure. Lesotho and Malawi proposesomething similar. Mozambique does not practicewhat it preaches, giving investor interests in customarylands more support than customary interests.The status of unregistered customary rights — morethan 90 percent of all rural landholding — is oftenambivalent and remains permissive, pending registration.Customary rights not registered are explicitly protectedin Uganda, Tanzania Mozambique and in a differentmanner, in Ghana. Customary owners in Côte d’Ivoirehave a short time limit within which rights must beregistered to be sustained. The movement of customarilyheld land out of government land/public land classes isclearest in Uganda, where public land is abolished, andTanzania, where it becomes ‘village land’. More than individualtitle is recognised. Family title is widely provided<strong>for</strong>, especially in Ethiopian law and Malawian policy.Adoption of procedures, limiting transfers of familyland without support of spouses, is provided in Ugandaand Rwanda and proposed in Malawi and Lesotho. Apresumption of spousal co-ownership exists in Tanzanialand law. Ef<strong>for</strong>ts to secure such a presumption failed inUganda. Ethiopia and Eritrea recognise male and femaleproperty rights distinctly.Sources: Alden Wily and Mbaya 2001; Alden Wily 2003cto education and awareness of property rightsamong <strong>the</strong> common people, which is discussed ina subsequent section.Measures to Make Property Systems More GenderEquitableThe UN Research Institute <strong>for</strong> Social Developmentnotes that <strong>the</strong>re has been ‘both considerableprogress throughout <strong>the</strong> 1990s in making<strong>for</strong>mal laws pertaining to land more genderequitable, as well as repeated failures in actuallyputting statutes to w<strong>ork</strong>.’ 111 Developing countrieshave, in many cases, enacted laws and policies toprovide women with greater rights to control andmanage property. Promising practices combineinstitutional measures, legal prescriptions andsocial policy:Special Units to Monitor Gender Issues. Policymakersshould establish special units to constantlymonitor gender issues and follow up on en<strong>for</strong>cement.In some environments, police services andcourt systems fail to en<strong>for</strong>ce women’s propertyrights. When property rights exist de jure but notde facto, policymakers face difficult choices:expend resources to better ensure en<strong>for</strong>cementor w<strong>ork</strong> to shift social norms. In countries withlimited capacity <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mer route is difficult. Inany country <strong>the</strong> latter is a major educational challenge.There is need <strong>for</strong> context-specific investigationof how best to shift social norms in ways that91


welcome women holding secure rights to property.This may well be a time-consuming process ofnorms evolving. It is an area in which much additionalresearch is needed.Joint Titling Ef<strong>for</strong>ts and Common Property. Governmentsshould register household propertyjointly in <strong>the</strong> name of both husband and wife. Byvirtue of marriage or sustained free union (domesticpartnership) real and moveable propertyheld or bought by <strong>the</strong> male partner should automaticallybe considered <strong>the</strong> co-property of <strong>the</strong>woman. Women usually do not have <strong>the</strong> means tocontribute 50 percent to <strong>the</strong> purchase of propertyin marriage.Inheritance. The primary way <strong>the</strong> poor acquireland is through <strong>the</strong> family and by inheritance. 112Many <strong>for</strong>mal or in<strong>for</strong>mal legal systems favour menin distributions made by inheritance. 113 In somecases, inheritance and succession laws providewidows with only temporary rights to use spousalproperty after <strong>the</strong>ir husbands die. These rulessubject women to <strong>the</strong> potential of property grabbing.Many countries have amended constitutionsor implemented legislation to guarantee <strong>the</strong> rightsof women to inherit property on an equitable basiswith men. However, in some countries may override<strong>the</strong>se provisions by custom or family law,while a number still maintain discriminatory provisionsin <strong>the</strong>ir legal codes. 114 Thus, <strong>for</strong> women, <strong>the</strong>existence of inheritance rules that call <strong>for</strong> maleand female heirs to receive equal consideration intestamentary distributions are an important stepon <strong>the</strong> path towards empowerment. There is someevidence that changing <strong>for</strong>mal inheritance lawsmay have <strong>the</strong> unintended consequence of promptingmen to specifically disinherit female heirs toavoid passing property to <strong>the</strong>m. 115Education and In<strong>for</strong>mation. Women may be unawareof <strong>the</strong>ir legally guaranteed property rights.This on-<strong>the</strong>-ground reality suggests that <strong>the</strong>re is acontinued need to educate women and girls as to<strong>the</strong>ir legal rights to own, use and transfer propertyand to communicate to society broadly <strong>the</strong> natureof <strong>the</strong>se rights.Intellectual Property Rights and <strong>the</strong> Rightsof Indigenous Peoples: The Task AheadIn most cases intellectual property is only indirectlylinked to <strong>the</strong> economic activities of <strong>the</strong>poor. However, in <strong>the</strong> case of indigenous people<strong>the</strong> issue of intellectual property is often relatedto <strong>for</strong>ms of dispossession and property misuse.Discussions have focused on a wide range ofissues, including moves to streng<strong>the</strong>n protectionof traditional cultural expressions (TCEs),traditional knowledge (TK) and genetic resources(GR) against misappropriation and misuse. 116 Inanalogy to this report’s focus on indigenous <strong>for</strong>msof tenure, ra<strong>the</strong>r than indigenous people as such,this section of <strong>the</strong> report pays attention to <strong>the</strong>se<strong>for</strong>ms of intellectual property rights ra<strong>the</strong>r than to<strong>the</strong> identification of <strong>the</strong>ir bearers. The UN HumanRights Council (Declaration on <strong>the</strong> Rights of IndigenousPeoples), <strong>the</strong> Convention on BiologicalDiversity 117 , <strong>the</strong> WTO TRIPS Council, UNCTAD,UNESCO, <strong>the</strong> FAO and WIPO have paid increasedattention to <strong>the</strong> protection of TCEs, TK, and GR.Some view intellectual property rights as a usefulinstrument <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> conservation of TK, GRand TCEs and as a tool <strong>for</strong> implementing a benefit-sharing.O<strong>the</strong>rs are more critical and fear atrivialisation of traditional cultures and possiblemisappropriation. O<strong>the</strong>rs still point to a fundamentalconflict between <strong>the</strong> very notion of intellectualproperty and <strong>the</strong> cultural values and moralperception of many indigenous populations.While indigenous notions of collective ownershipand trans-generational custodianship might becompatible with <strong>the</strong> overall idea of (intellectual)92


property, some indigenous peoples aim to preventappropriation of natural and cultural resources.In such cases, <strong>the</strong>re is a fundamental conflictbetween indigenous rights and (intellectual) property.In fundamental opposition to some indigenouscultures, many intellectual property systemsrecognise rights on inventions pertaining to livingmatter. In conventional patent systems, matterknown to <strong>the</strong> public belongs to <strong>the</strong> so-called publicdomain, thus preventing <strong>the</strong>ir protection andallowing <strong>the</strong>ir free use by anyone. Worse <strong>for</strong> someindigenous people, <strong>the</strong> concept of public domainassociated with traditional intellectual propertylaws has allowed <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> appropriation of GR andTK <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> development of inventions that aresubsequently patented.Intellectual Property Rights in Context. The rightsof indigenous peoples depend on and interactwith a wide range of o<strong>the</strong>r measures and policies,such as land tenure, environmental laws andprotection of endangered species, health, foodand agriculture, water quality, cultural heritageprotection, access to and exploitation of naturalresources, environmental management, and soilconservation. Within this broader horizon, intellectualproperty rights may play a positive role inencouraging creation or protection of indigenousrights. Such a role includes, <strong>for</strong> example, <strong>the</strong>protection and disclosure of new intellectual creationsthrough <strong>the</strong> laws of patents and industrialdesigns or avoiding confusion and deception andpreventing unfair competition through <strong>the</strong> protectionof trademarks and geographical indications.Equally relevant are <strong>the</strong> safeguarding of <strong>the</strong> integrityof, and rights of attribution to, certain w<strong>ork</strong>sand creations through moral rights’ protection incopyright, and <strong>the</strong> protection of undisclosed in<strong>for</strong>mationfrom bad faith use or appropriation. Anexample of <strong>the</strong> use of intellectual property rightsin <strong>the</strong> protection of traditional knowledge relatesto traditional medicines in <strong>the</strong> People’s Republicof China, in respect of which several thousandpatents have been granted in past years. 118Way Forward. Notwithstanding useful aspects,many questions remain as well as importantconcerns:1. Conventional intellectual property rights mightnot offer indigenous peoples adequate protectionin situations where <strong>the</strong> resource, knowledgeor cultural expression is already publiclyknown. In this case, <strong>the</strong> creation of sui generissystems of protection is needed.2. The overall purpose of intellectual propertyrights <strong>for</strong> indigenous people in both positiveprotection and negative protection needs to befur<strong>the</strong>r evaluated.3. Existing and future systems must ensure that<strong>the</strong>y do not contribute to an undue misappropriationof certain intellectual assets of indigenouspeoples.International Dimension. In addition, because GR/TK and TCEs are often exploited in countries differentfrom <strong>the</strong> countries of origin, <strong>the</strong>re are callsto establish international instruments that take accountof <strong>the</strong> intangible nature and cross-boundarynature of those components of indigenous life andheritage. This will require examination of complexissues, such as <strong>the</strong> question of ownership/custodianshipof rights, <strong>for</strong>m of protection to be granted,ways <strong>for</strong> ensuring nationals of one country toenjoy rights in <strong>for</strong>eign countries, question of fairand equitable benefit-sharing in <strong>the</strong> internationalcontext, recognition of personal or moral rights ofindigenous people, ensuring that known resourcesor knowledge already in <strong>the</strong> public domain cannotbe subject to intellectual property rights, and <strong>the</strong>need <strong>for</strong> enhanced international cooperation inareas such as mutual in<strong>for</strong>mation, registration andmanagement of rights, among o<strong>the</strong>rs.93


The Intergovernmental Committee on IntellectualProperty and Genetic Resources, Traditionalknowledge and folklore (IGC), established byWIPO Member States in 2000 has adopted an inclusiveapproach. The IGC has been exploring <strong>the</strong>potential of protecting rights of indigenous peoplesthrough conventional intellectual propertyrights and through sui generis systems 119 , w<strong>ork</strong>ingtowards an understanding of how best to protectTK and TCEs against misappropriation, clarifyingissues such as <strong>the</strong> positive and negative protectionand w<strong>ork</strong>ing on a better understanding of <strong>the</strong>international dimension of such protection. TheIGC process has resulted in draft objectives andprinciples <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> legal protection of TK and TCEsagainst misappropriation and misuse. 120Re<strong>for</strong>ming Property Governancein view of <strong>the</strong> Least AdvantagedCustomerThe property system is upheld by a system ofgovernance which includes <strong>the</strong> institutional orderof <strong>the</strong> state, procedural rules and relationshipsof interaction between state and stakeholders,ranging from property registration, spatial planning,zoning, taxing and o<strong>the</strong>r aspects of propertymanagement, and en<strong>for</strong>cement. Since a propertysystem with general deficits will not produce beneficialresults targeted to <strong>the</strong> poor, this sectionpresents broader re<strong>for</strong>m combined with measuresthat particularly promote <strong>the</strong> inclusion of <strong>the</strong> poorin effective property rights protection. 121Changing LegislationRe<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>the</strong> property system to produce tangiblebenefits <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor might imply <strong>the</strong> need tochange <strong>the</strong> law or introduce new legislation. 122Such procedures are time consuming and hard topredict in <strong>the</strong>ir final outcome due to political contingencies.It is thus advisable to first design <strong>the</strong>most urgent policy measures needed to improve<strong>the</strong> property access and security <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor, and<strong>the</strong>n to assess if <strong>the</strong> legal basis <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> measuresis sufficient. If this is <strong>the</strong> case, it might be moreefficient to seek improvement within a given legalframew<strong>ork</strong>. In many cases, however, <strong>the</strong> implementationof pro-poor property rights, especially<strong>for</strong> customary owners and women, requires legal(statutory or customary) or even constitutionalre<strong>for</strong>m. 123Agovernment’s large-scale ownership of land,its ability to impose planning restrictionsand to expropriate without adequate compensation,contributes to tenure insecurity and oftendemands legal re<strong>for</strong>m as well. Re<strong>for</strong>m mightbe undertaken with clear goals of what <strong>the</strong> newpro-poor property law should look like: allowingprivate individual or group owned property of landunder customary tenure; allowing <strong>the</strong> franchisingof micro-enterprise with limited liability; allowing<strong>the</strong> use of moveable property as collateral; creatinglegal figures of associational property whichallow <strong>the</strong> poor to pool and exit property; protectingwomen’s property in and outside <strong>the</strong> marriageand in inheritance; restricting eminent domain,and introducing protective pro-poor zoning laws,among o<strong>the</strong>rs. However, <strong>the</strong> inclusive procedureof making, implementing, and monitoring <strong>the</strong>consequences of <strong>the</strong> law by fur<strong>the</strong>r regulations,as well as securing sustained support <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> lawfrom different stakeholders and agents, are asimportant as <strong>the</strong> content of <strong>the</strong> law itself. Politicalconstellations might make sweeping andcomprehensive re<strong>for</strong>ms possible and hence advisablein some contexts. If not, it is also possibleto approach <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m of property law in a moreprocess-oriented manner. The following guidingprinciples have been useful in endeavours in differentnational contexts, where a one-time sweepingre<strong>for</strong>m was politically impossible:94


• Where consensus is hard to obtain and/ormedium-term effects hard to anticipate, apragmatic and incremental approach to legalre<strong>for</strong>m is often <strong>the</strong> best approach.• Legal and regulatory re<strong>for</strong>ms can be obtainedwith <strong>the</strong> support of beneficiaries. But <strong>the</strong>irshort-term benefits have to be assessed inlight of <strong>the</strong> provision of public goods and longterm effects. 124• Legal and regulatory obstacles can be identifiedwith <strong>the</strong> help of communities. 125• Applying a learning-by-doing approach to legaland regulatory change is beneficial <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>progress of <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m project. 126In ef<strong>for</strong>ts to merge legality and legitimacy to solidifyeffective impact and equity of property law,communication and consensus-building measureshave proven to be of vital importance. Given <strong>the</strong>political sensitivity of property issues, securingand maintaining high-level consensus and commitmentto property re<strong>for</strong>m is critical, especiallyas such support can falter during changes in <strong>the</strong>political administration, <strong>for</strong> example. There<strong>for</strong>e, aconsensus-building and communication strategymust be designed and implemented to sustainbroad support.Re<strong>for</strong>m Priorities in Land and Real PropertyAdministrationA land and real property administration systemthat is generally dysfunctional will not all of asudden produce targeted measures that benefit<strong>the</strong> poor. It is <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e advisable to make <strong>the</strong>system as a whole more efficient and friendly to<strong>the</strong> least advantaged customer. The combinationof organisational simplicity and accessibility significantlyimproves <strong>the</strong> efficiency of registrationand administration, <strong>the</strong>reby increasing tenuresecurity of broad sectors of <strong>the</strong> population and,as a result, public support. Effectiveness of legalprovisions depends on availability of institutions<strong>for</strong> en<strong>for</strong>cement. In particular, many of <strong>the</strong> expectedeconomic benefits (especially exchangeand use of land as collateral) from secure landrights will not materialise unless a well-functioning,transparent, and accessible land administrationsystem is in place. 127Simplicity. Every political entity should only haveone or a strict minimum of well-coordinatedproperty administration agencies. The integrationof <strong>the</strong> cadastre, property, intellectual and commercialregistries contributes to improved outputlegitimacy and investment climate. Experienceworldwide shows that delays and tenure insecurity,due to rivalries and conflicting interests, areinevitable when a number of competing agenciesare simultaneously responsible <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> implementationof property rights. 128Accessibility. Local Presence. The locations of<strong>the</strong> agency should be as decentralised as possibleand easily accessible <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor who are unableto bear <strong>the</strong> costs of travelling long distances inorder to register or transfer property.Reduced Transaction Costs. Ef<strong>for</strong>ts to reduce <strong>the</strong>number of days it takes to <strong>for</strong>mally register propertycan have a positive effect in terms of reducingtransaction costs. So too can reducing <strong>the</strong> numberof steps buyers and sellers must follow be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>for</strong>maltransfers take place. However, in addition tosuch changes, countries should be encouraged totake additional steps to reduce transactions costsin property markets, mainly in organising publicand private legal services in a pro-poor manner. 129A key reason <strong>for</strong> land sales to be driven into in<strong>for</strong>mality,which can over time threaten <strong>the</strong> integrityof <strong>the</strong> registry in<strong>for</strong>mation, is <strong>the</strong> desire to avoidhigh levels of taxation, mainly in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of stampduties, or <strong>the</strong> need to make in<strong>for</strong>mal payments. In95


addition to setting clear fee structures that are wellpublicized, reduction of stamp duties, possiblyby replacing <strong>the</strong>m with a land tax to be assessedat <strong>the</strong> local level, would be desirable. Such a tax,complemented by a capital gains tax if necessary,could encourage productive land use and reduceincentives <strong>for</strong> speculative land accumulation, thusmaking productivity-enhancing outcomes fromland sales markets more likely. Moreover, adjudicationand dispute settlement can be embeddedin a cost-saving, community-based participatoryprocess. It is cost-effective <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> state to investin <strong>the</strong> capacity of a pool of potential conciliatorsat a community or district level of government. 130For any first-time registration of land rights to havea lasting and pro-poor effect, it needs to be integratedwith systems to maintain registry records upto date in a cost-effective way that is in line withwhat users are able and willing to pay.Modern GPS and In<strong>for</strong>mation Technology. Inmany contexts of <strong>the</strong> developing world, <strong>the</strong> technicalcosts of titling and land registration havebeen considerably reduced by computerisationand GPS systems. 131 Modern technology can helpto improve transparency and at <strong>the</strong> same timemake administration more accessible. 132 As <strong>the</strong>purpose of land registries is to give public noticeof land ownership and transactions, makingregistry in<strong>for</strong>mation available publicly on <strong>the</strong> Internetand promoting Internet access can reducetransaction cost and by allowing independentcross-checks, greatly increase public confidencein <strong>the</strong>m. The transition to an all-digital, internetenabledland registration system is not withoutpitfalls. Corruption can easily increase in <strong>the</strong>early phase, because <strong>the</strong> opportunity <strong>for</strong> altering<strong>the</strong> records be<strong>for</strong>e digitisation is high. The introductionof all-digital and internet-based registrysystems has to be carefully prepared and preemptiveaction to <strong>the</strong> altering of records taken.Corruption is reduced dramatically once <strong>the</strong> systemsare operational. 133Financial Self-sustainability. Land administrationinstitutions will be viable in <strong>the</strong> long term andindependent from political pressure only if <strong>the</strong>ycan sustain <strong>the</strong>ir recurrent operations financially,without charging more than <strong>the</strong> poor are able topay. This in turn is a precondition <strong>for</strong> all <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rbenefits from land administration to materialise.Separation of Powers of Land Registration andPublic Land Management. Land administration,i.e. all matters relating to land rights should beindependent from <strong>the</strong> authorities in charge ofstate land management and use. This reduces <strong>the</strong>possibility of abusive practices where <strong>the</strong> state isonly <strong>the</strong> means through which individuals pursue<strong>the</strong>ir particular interests and of which <strong>the</strong> poorare usually <strong>the</strong> first victims.Increasing Transparency in Public Land Use andPlanningGovernments’ large-scale ownership of land,its ability to impose planning restrictionsand to expropriate without adequate compensationalso contributes to tenure insecurity of <strong>the</strong>poor who have no government lobby. 134Define Government’s Land Rights and Duties andEstablish an Inventory of Government Land: Invirtually all countries, <strong>the</strong> government nominallyowns large amounts of land. However, <strong>the</strong> extentof such claims and associated rights and obligationsare often not well defined. At worst, thisencourages sell-offs of public assets to <strong>the</strong> wellconnectedleading to a speculative accumulationof large non-productive land holdings or concessions.Keeping public land at <strong>the</strong> necessary minimumand defining <strong>the</strong> responsibilities of differentlevels of government in terms of managing publicland would be a first step that should be followedby a inventorying and registering of state land96


and <strong>the</strong> establishment of transparent administrativeprocesses at all levels <strong>for</strong> granting, selling,and leasing of state lands.Strictly Circumscribe Conditions <strong>for</strong> Expropriationof Land: As transferring land from agricultureto non-agricultural or urban uses is a corollaryof economic development, an important issuethat undermines tenure security in much of <strong>the</strong>developing world — and which has often causedgreat hardship to <strong>for</strong>mer land owners — is <strong>the</strong>government’s far-reaching ability to expropriateland with real compensation often far below marketrates. The threat of expropriation has servedto undermine tenure security and investment andhas also led to in<strong>for</strong>mal sales in anticipation ofexpropriation that often invited corruption andshady property deals involving state agencies.Productivity was impaired as <strong>the</strong> state apparatushad often nei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> means nor <strong>the</strong> incentivesto invest in or effectively use <strong>the</strong> land acquired,<strong>the</strong>reby often leaving <strong>the</strong> potentially most valuableland undeveloped. One reason <strong>for</strong> this is that,in many countries, even land <strong>for</strong> private uses willfirst have to be acquired by <strong>the</strong> state, somethingthat can greatly increase <strong>the</strong> transaction costfaced by private investors. Eliminating such rules,constraining expropriation to cases where a narrowlydefined public purpose is at stake, whileallowing land owners or users to negotiate directlywith interested parties in <strong>the</strong> remainder of <strong>the</strong>cases (with <strong>the</strong> possibility to draw on mediation ifneeded) can eliminate a key source of uncertaintyand corruption.Zoning and City PlanningZoning and planning is one of <strong>the</strong> main causes ofexclusion of <strong>the</strong> poor from legal and <strong>for</strong>mal cityand peri-urban development processes. On <strong>the</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong> right use of zoning and spatialplanning can become a <strong>for</strong>midable instrument oflegal empowerment. 135 Although this is perhapsmost commonly a feature of <strong>the</strong> rural-urban zoneof transition, it is also a feature within urban areas,and within rural areas. 136 Especially changesin use from agriculture to urban residential orcommercial purposes usually multiply <strong>the</strong> valueof land significantly, and consequently augment<strong>the</strong> potential <strong>for</strong> abuse. Peri-urban areas needto be better planned if <strong>the</strong>y are to be more effectivein promoting sustainable pro-poor urbandevelopment. The ambit of interventions hasto expand beyond slum upgrading and tenureregularisation to defining <strong>the</strong> urban developmentframew<strong>ork</strong> within which access to land and landdevelopment rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor becomes possible.137 Spatial and urban planning can be a majordriving <strong>for</strong>ce behind higher living standards andwealth generation. 138 The relevance <strong>for</strong> urbanplanning is heightened in <strong>the</strong> idea that responsibility,incentives and ownership should be alignedto maximise desired ends. 139Eliminate Inappropriate Planning Regulations.Overcoming extra-legality in urban areas will beimpossible without a careful review of planningregulations - some of which, such as minimumlot sizes, were designed with <strong>the</strong> explicit purposeof segregating property markets. While regulationsmay be introduced with more benevolentgoals, <strong>the</strong>y may none<strong>the</strong>less affect <strong>the</strong> poor negativelyand, through <strong>the</strong>ir impacts on urban <strong>for</strong>ms,be environmentally and socially harmful. Whileit will be dangerous to generalise, in practice <strong>the</strong>only reason <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> continued existence of harmfulregulations is ei<strong>the</strong>r limited knowledge onalternatives or <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>y benefit powerfulvested interest groups who are generally not <strong>the</strong>poor.Establish Transparent and Participatory Land UsePlanning: Even if rules are well justified, in manycountries, land use planning follows non-transparentand highly centralised processes. This97


implies that rules often have little relevance <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> reality of <strong>the</strong> poor. Focusing central ef<strong>for</strong>ts ondefining clear per<strong>for</strong>mance criteria <strong>for</strong> land useand ways of en<strong>for</strong>cement while leaving detailedplanning to <strong>the</strong> local level are likely to result inplans that focus on relevant issues, have higherlocal acceptance, and thus stand a better chanceof actually being implemented.Avoiding Ghetto-<strong>for</strong>mation by Mixed Neighbourhoods.New and ‘good old urbanism’ definesalternatives <strong>for</strong> urban growth and communitiesbased on concepts of mixed neighbourhoods,mixed land use, diversity and public identity.These concepts w<strong>ork</strong> towards integrating urbanismand environmentalism, and joining ra<strong>the</strong>rthan segregating <strong>the</strong> poor and ethnic minoritiesin diverse communities. 140Special Social Interest Zones. Forming mixedneighbourhoods does not substitute <strong>for</strong> additionalzoning and planning measures that canw<strong>ork</strong> to improve existing slums. Here, specialinterest zones can create protective and empoweringenvironments of residence and businessactivity <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> urban and peri-urban poor.In Brazil several planning measures have beentaken to provide secure conditions of livingand livelihood <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor. For instance, urbanzones which have favelas, corticos (collectivehousing, popular subdivisions), and o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>msof housing and home-based economic activitieson vacant lands, can be declared as ZEIS orSpecial Social Interest Zones under municipallaw. Special rules are drafted and simplifiedprocedures adopted <strong>for</strong> each ZEIS by a localcommittee <strong>for</strong> regularisation of land occupationand use of land by <strong>the</strong> poor. ZEIS havenow been adopted relatively successfully by anumber of Brazilian cities. 141Conditionality <strong>for</strong> Private Developers. One importantprovision, <strong>for</strong> instance of <strong>the</strong> progressiveUrban Development and Housing Act of 1992 of<strong>the</strong> Philippines 142 , is Balanced Housing Developmentwhereby developers of proposed subdivisionsare required to develop 20 percent of <strong>the</strong>land <strong>for</strong> housing low income communities. Asimilar provision of <strong>the</strong> Government of <strong>the</strong> Indianstate of Madhya Pradesh enacted as part of <strong>the</strong>Colonisers’ Act requires 15 percent of <strong>the</strong> land tobe reserved <strong>for</strong> without shelter households or paymentof a sum equivalent to <strong>the</strong> officially determinedprice of <strong>the</strong> land to be reserved. The policyhas made land available <strong>for</strong> housing more than6,000 poor households in central city locations in<strong>the</strong> city of Bhopal alone and substantial funds <strong>for</strong>land procurement and development. 143Density Mixed Use Zones legitimise densely built,small plots and home based businesses. Thedraft Nation Slum Policy of India 144 proposes tointegrate in<strong>for</strong>mal settlements into city planningby designating <strong>the</strong>m as high-density mixed usezones, to legitimise densely built, small plotsand home-based businesses. It also proposesthat only slums in environmental risk areas andland use zones <strong>for</strong> essential services and facilitiesshould be relocated. All o<strong>the</strong>rs should beregularised and <strong>the</strong>ir land use zoning should bechanged to high-density mixed-use. The NationalHousing and Habitat Policy propose that landshould be zoned <strong>for</strong> housing <strong>the</strong> poor in city masterplans. 145Reversing <strong>the</strong> Development Sequence in SlumUpgrading. The strategy of reversing <strong>the</strong> developmentsequence by first allotting secured plotswith only bare minimum services, with provision<strong>for</strong> incremental improvement gives <strong>the</strong> poor sustainableownership and participation in <strong>the</strong> valueincrease of property. Such measures match <strong>the</strong>af<strong>for</strong>dability of allottees and assure that even <strong>the</strong>poorest get access to secure land and housing,98


which develop into a fully serviced neighbourhoodin <strong>the</strong> longer term. 146Supporting Street Entrepreneurs. Many Indianstates have adopted <strong>the</strong> Central Government’sNational Street Vendors’ Policy of 2004, aimedat recognising and planning <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malbut widespread activity of hawking and vendingin cities and to provide basic facilities such asspace, water and sanitation and access to credit.147 The policy itself was framed after more thana decade of lobbying by NGOs and street vendorsfederations. Under <strong>the</strong> policy local governmentsof cities such as Bhopal, Hyderabad, Kolkata andDelhi have delineated Hawkers’ Zones. Initialindications are that this has ended harassment of<strong>the</strong> poor and provided <strong>the</strong>m with security to carryout income earning activities. 148Involving Stakeholders in Spatial Planning. Thestrategy of using a survey to make claims anddraw attention of <strong>the</strong> authorities to poor livingconditions was first used in Mumbai in 1987 bypavement dwellers supported by The Society <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> Promotion of Area Resource Centres (SPARC).This was followed by women pavement dwellersidentifying potential vacant lands in <strong>the</strong> city<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir relocation, and <strong>for</strong>cing <strong>the</strong> city governmentto act. This strategy paved <strong>the</strong> way <strong>for</strong> civicauthorities to recognise <strong>the</strong> role of civil societyorganisations in developing responsive housingsolutions <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor, and later participating inframing <strong>the</strong> relocation and rehabilitation policy<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> World Bank funded Mumbai Urban TransportProject. Similar initiatives are taking placein Thailand with <strong>the</strong> support of CODI (CommunityOrganisations Development Institute), which is agovernment organisation created to facilitate localhousing improvement and livelihood initiatives ofcommunity groups. 149Implementation and Dispute SettlementExpand Options <strong>for</strong> Conflict Resolution. Implementationis a decisive element of propertyrights governance. Where it fails, it can nullifyor considerably reduce <strong>the</strong> effectiveness of allo<strong>the</strong>r elements. Developing countries are oftenat loss of stable and predictable implementationand dispute settlement institutions. Traditionalinstitutions can resolve some <strong>for</strong>ms of localiseddisputes. But <strong>the</strong>y are not well equipped to addressdisputes that cut across groups from differentcommunities (e.g. nomads and sedentaryagriculturalists), across ethnic boundaries, or thatare between individuals and <strong>the</strong> state. Even so,expanding <strong>the</strong> range of options to resolve landconflicts systematically and out of court can havelarge benefits, especially <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor and <strong>for</strong>women who o<strong>the</strong>rwise are often unable to en<strong>for</strong>ce<strong>the</strong>ir legal rights. 150 In many contexts, Third PartyArbitration Courts (TPACs) can be considered aneconomic and social success. These mechanismsoffer effective protection of property rights and/oreffective resolutions of disputes over contestedproperty arrangements, especially <strong>for</strong> disenfranchisedwomen.Alternative dispute resolution is very promisingbut has its pitfalls. In general, successof alternative dispute resolution depends oncertain standards and practices. An importantcondition is <strong>the</strong> right of poor people to appointjudges of <strong>the</strong>ir choice <strong>for</strong> dispute resolution. Butit is equally imperative that <strong>the</strong> alternative disputeresolution mechanism be linked to <strong>for</strong>malen<strong>for</strong>cement and not operate totally outside <strong>the</strong>realm of <strong>the</strong> legal system. Rules have to be craftedin accordance with <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal legal and in<strong>for</strong>malsocial context. If supported by aid, financialsustainability should be guaranteed <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> timeafter donor support has stopped. 15199Include Property Issues in Post-conflict Settle-


ments and Natural Disaster Management. In <strong>the</strong>many situations where land issues have oftenbeen at <strong>the</strong> root of broader civil strife, failure todevote proper attention to <strong>the</strong>se issues, includingways of managing land access by returnees, caneasily undermine <strong>the</strong>ir sustainability of such settlementsand sow <strong>the</strong> seeds <strong>for</strong> violence. Learningfrom successful examples to address land-relatedgrievances and settle large numbers of people ina rapid and decentralised way toge<strong>the</strong>r with waysthat will prevent limited conflicts from festeringand escalating into larger ones can help to avoidmuch broader clashes, often with very damaginghumanitarian and economic consequences. 152Re<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>the</strong> Property System asa Market of Assets <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> PoorA functional property system allows <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> trans<strong>for</strong>mationof assets into fungible property rightsand <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> exchange of those rights in open markets.In order to benefit <strong>the</strong> poor, real propertyand credit markets need to be developed and<strong>the</strong>y need to be regulated where <strong>the</strong>y systematicallyw<strong>ork</strong> against <strong>the</strong> poor. In general, re<strong>for</strong>msshould aim at opening <strong>the</strong> door to <strong>the</strong> poor to abroadened asset base. Guaranteeing <strong>the</strong> poor <strong>the</strong>right to property and to leverage property in <strong>the</strong>market is a multi-stakeholder task best achievedby close partnerships between <strong>the</strong> state, <strong>the</strong> privatesector and civil society.Market DevelopmentA Pro-poor Framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> Land Sale Markets.Historically, most land sales were due to distressthat required defaulting landowners to cede controlof <strong>the</strong>ir land to moneylenders, who amassedhuge amounts of lands. 153 However, data onland sales over 20 years in India illustrate <strong>the</strong>importance of land sales markets and of beingin <strong>the</strong> land markets: First, <strong>the</strong>y transferred landto better cultivators and from land-abundant toland-scarce households, allowing <strong>the</strong> land-scarceto improve <strong>the</strong>ir welfare 154 without making sellersworse off. Sales markets were indeed thinner,more affected by life-cycle events, and lessredistributive than those <strong>for</strong> rentals. Land salesmarkets helped purchasers, many of whom were<strong>for</strong>merly landless, to accumulate non-land assetsand significantly enhance <strong>the</strong>ir welfare. 155 Ef<strong>for</strong>tsat redistributive land re<strong>for</strong>m will need to aim atcomplementing what market <strong>for</strong>ces are achieving.Market development with <strong>the</strong> poor in mind oughtto be pursued by:• Granting freedom of contract, definition ofobligations, remedies <strong>for</strong> failing to fulfil obligationsand <strong>for</strong> terminating obligations orderly,guidance on how to conclude a contract, definitionof <strong>for</strong>ms of contract (oral or written);identification of invalid transactions.• <strong>Making</strong> land purchase and sale easier <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>poor by minimising conditions such as <strong>for</strong>maleducation or experience in agriculture. Providemodel sales contracts <strong>the</strong> poor can rely on.• Keeping leasing rules simple and clear.• Reducing transaction costs <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor byavoiding overly precise mapping, avoiding repetitionof platting parcels, not covering initialplatting fees <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor.• Avoiding notary fees <strong>for</strong> small transactions;keeping registration fees and transaction taxesvery low <strong>for</strong> small transactions and exemptingnew and small land owners from registrationfees and tax; putting to severe need testand cost-benefit analysis every administrativeintervention into land deals and eliminatinginterventions which do not stand <strong>the</strong> test.• Granting preferential rights to buy to co-owners,neighbours, or leaseholders of land.100


Box 5 Sale of land: examples oflegal issuesIn <strong>the</strong> collective certificate of land ownership award(CLOA) system of <strong>the</strong> Philippines not even a majorityof <strong>the</strong> collective can decide to sell, mortgage or use<strong>the</strong> title as collateral to obtain <strong>for</strong>mal credit. Under<strong>the</strong> Comprehensive Agrarian Re<strong>for</strong>m Program of <strong>the</strong>same country, <strong>the</strong>re was a prohibition on any <strong>for</strong>mof transfer within 10 years of award. In addition, afive-hectare ceiling on ownership was set and onlyqualified farmers can buy awarded land. This didnot stop but increase transfers and pushed <strong>the</strong>minto extra-legality with adverse consequences <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor (NCLEP Philippines 2006). In Armenia,a three-year moratorium was imposed after landprivatisation in 1991. In Ukraine, a 6-year salesmoratorium will expire in 2005, but many exemptionshave circumvented this measure. A Kyrgyzmoratorium on <strong>the</strong> sale of agricultural land was putinto place when land was privatised and allocated,but it was subsequently lifted in September 2001.The Moldovan Land Code contained a 10-year moratoriumon sales that was declared unconstitutionaland lifted in late 1996. Some countries have attemptedto protect new landowners from <strong>the</strong> dangerof mortgage <strong>for</strong>eclosure by setting moratoria onmortgages; <strong>for</strong> example, a 1997 Russian law prohibitedmortgages on agricultural land (Russian <strong>Law</strong>On Mortgage 1997).Ceilings of ownership w<strong>ork</strong> in some contexts <strong>for</strong>some time but have adverse consequences <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor in <strong>the</strong> long run. 156 Sales moratoria areconsidered a successful practice, provided <strong>the</strong>time is used <strong>for</strong> public education on land values,financial literacy, and participation in land markets.157 Where <strong>the</strong> moratoria extend over a longeramount of time, <strong>the</strong>y install barriers which do notcorrespond to <strong>the</strong> needs and capabilities of <strong>the</strong>poor. Notwithstanding prohibitions, land pawningtransactions, direct sales, sales through waiver ofrights, sales through pawning, and sales throughland conversion arrangements are sometimeswidespread. Ultimately, <strong>the</strong>se transfers augment<strong>the</strong> risk of losing land rights.Bringing <strong>the</strong> Poor into <strong>the</strong> Market: Opportunitiesand Responsibilities of Medium and Large Companies.Large companies, regardless of <strong>the</strong>ir industry,can stimulate local markets and increase <strong>the</strong> valueof <strong>the</strong> real, moveable, and equity property of <strong>the</strong>poor by enabling <strong>the</strong>m to become active participantsin <strong>the</strong>ir chains of value addition. Inclusionof <strong>the</strong> poor in <strong>the</strong> value chain creates businessopportunities <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> next decade. Designing businessmodels to address this challenge opens newopportunities <strong>for</strong> company growth as well as <strong>for</strong>broadening <strong>the</strong> assets base <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor. Manybusiness leaders now believe that <strong>the</strong> planet’s poormust become part of company growth strategy,and that <strong>the</strong> presence of <strong>the</strong>ir enterprise in a developingnation will be crucial to <strong>the</strong>ir long-termsuccess, with <strong>the</strong> advantage going to early movers.To be successful, however, such projects must bebased on <strong>the</strong> real needs, capabilities, and realitiesof low-income communities. 158The focus on business implies focus on profitability.If <strong>the</strong> projects realise <strong>the</strong> goal of profitability,this means that <strong>the</strong>y have no limited, fixed budget.The new business can thus become replicable andlead to a remarkable empowering impact. Providingbusiness solutions <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor and with <strong>the</strong>poor can cover a multitude of activities. The guidingprinciple is that companies should engage <strong>the</strong>poor in a business relationship that relates directlyto <strong>the</strong>ir core commercial operations.The poor may be customers and can profit frommore af<strong>for</strong>dable products. 159 The poor may also bebusiness partners, suppliers, and/or distributors.The poor can be considered as partners creatingadded value at every stage of <strong>the</strong> delivery of aservice/product designed to serve <strong>the</strong>ir needs. 160By bringing small entrepreneurs and local small101


and medium enterprises (SMEs) into <strong>the</strong>ir valuechains, established international business canempower <strong>the</strong> poor and accelerate skill transfer. 161Companies addressing basic needs, such as utilitiesand health care providers, can contribute significantlyto local development by expanding <strong>the</strong>irservices to more low-income communities. 162Extractive companies often find <strong>the</strong>mselves doingbusiness with low income governments andcommunities through <strong>the</strong>ir drilling and miningcontracts, licences, fees and royalties. They thushave a major influence on <strong>the</strong> paths of developmentof poor countries. 163Moveable and Intangible Property: A MissingPiece of <strong>the</strong> Development PuzzleAlthough many of <strong>the</strong> citizens of <strong>the</strong> developingworld lack secure rights to use and transfer realproperty, most of <strong>the</strong>m actually do own some tangible(moveable) or intangible property (businessskills and in<strong>for</strong>mational schemes). 164 Peasantsand urban street entrepreneurs alike use moveableproperty as means of production. To <strong>the</strong> extentthat this type of property is held securely and canbe used to access credit to create and grow businesses,<strong>the</strong> poor will have increased opportunities.Collateralising moveable and intangible propertycan play an important role in a nation’s developmentstrategy. 165 In many parts of <strong>the</strong> developedworld, a broad array of personal property, bothtangible and intangible, can be used legally ascollateral to secure a loan, whereas in many partsof <strong>the</strong> developing world, only a small fraction ofthis property can be used as collateral. 166 Thereis evidence that expanding <strong>the</strong> number of itemsthat can be used legally as collateral reduces <strong>the</strong>cost of credit. And because more people can borrowif more types of property can be used as collateralcredit markets become more competitive.Lenders pass along <strong>the</strong>ir savings to customers,by reducing fees and offering lower interest ratesand competitive <strong>for</strong>ces also help to keep <strong>the</strong> priceof credit lower than it o<strong>the</strong>rwise would be. 167For small-scale enterprises, such cost savings canhave a major positive impact. SME entrepreneursof developing countries routinely list financingand access to credit as <strong>the</strong>ir major obstacle togrowth. 168 To <strong>the</strong> extent that collateral law re<strong>for</strong>mmakes borrowing easier and less costly, it couldvery well serve to promote SME development inmany countries.Creating a public moveable and intangible propertyregistry (or, more simply, a registry listingstolen items), and enacting legal re<strong>for</strong>ms thatmake it easier to use moveable and intangibleproperty as collateral, will expand access to credit<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor. Experience in a variety of developingcountries (one should include here Georgia,Madagascar, Colombia, Albania, and Bosnia,among o<strong>the</strong>rs) suggests that <strong>the</strong>re are at leastthree important legal re<strong>for</strong>ms that would serve toallow <strong>the</strong> poor to leverage movable and intangibleproperty. These are:• Allowing <strong>for</strong> freedom of contract in loan agreementsso that borrowers are free to use moveableand intangible property as collateral.Lenders and borrowers should be free to determine,between <strong>the</strong>mselves, which property willbe used as collateral <strong>for</strong> a loan.• Provide secured creditors with first prioritywith pledged collateral. Evidence that a creditoris secured may be obtained from a collateralregistry.• Creditors should be empowered to en<strong>for</strong>ce collateralagreements quickly by means of summaryproceedings.If developing nations allowed borrowers greaterfreedom to use moveable and intangible property102


as collateral more of <strong>the</strong> poor would be able tocreate credit histories. For borrowers, <strong>the</strong> greatestrisk is losing real property. With moveableproperty, <strong>the</strong> loss is proportionate and collateralcan be better matched to <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> loan. 169The poor may be understandably hesitant to use<strong>the</strong> title to <strong>the</strong>ir home as collateral <strong>for</strong> a loan, butif <strong>the</strong>y can use a refrigerator as collateral, <strong>the</strong>ymay be able to borrow smaller sums that will help<strong>the</strong>m start or build a business or send a child toschool.Creating a moveable and intangible registry isless expensive than <strong>the</strong> creation of land registries— it may take as little as $500,000 and no morethan two years of time to create a self-financingmoveable and intangible property registry. 170 Fordeveloping countries, amending laws and regulationson collateral, in conjunction with <strong>the</strong> establishmentof registry may be a feasible, cost-effectiveand pro-poor development strategy.When conditions of instability and conflict exist,when <strong>the</strong> rule of law is absent, and when o<strong>the</strong>rinstitutional structures do not appear to be functioning,one should expect that re<strong>for</strong>m aimed atimproving <strong>the</strong> security and usefulness of moveableand intangible property would not, by itself,create economic growth.Equity Based Asset-Building <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> PoorCreating Property Value <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor by ShareholderSystemsInnovative <strong>for</strong>ms of non-real estate can extend<strong>the</strong> asset base of <strong>the</strong> poor and non-credit basedshareholder ownership, enabled by <strong>the</strong> fungiblenature of property rights. Unlike land and housing,<strong>the</strong> reproductive potential of non-tangibleobjects of property is potentially unlimited. While<strong>the</strong> private sector is at <strong>the</strong> heart of this enterprise,<strong>the</strong> state has an important role to play inguaranteeing contracts and transactions and increating an overarching enabling framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong>equity based pro-poor business and banking practices.Natural Resources Requiring Capital IntensiveExtraction, Treatment and Distribution. In <strong>the</strong> caseof state co-ownership of fossil energy reserves, <strong>the</strong>local populations should be included in <strong>the</strong> chainof value addition by tradable shares in generalpublic funds. Many of <strong>the</strong> poor people of <strong>the</strong> worldlive in lands rich in natural resources that are controlledthrough government ownership. Distributingshares to populations or o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>m of ownershipparticipation in state owned companies exploitingnatural resources will provide <strong>the</strong> poor with capitalthat can, among o<strong>the</strong>r things, propel <strong>the</strong> expansionof small businesses. An alternative option is distributingtitles to special funds created by governmentsto invest profits yielded by commodities.Recent experience in Kenya is illustrative of how<strong>the</strong> poor are willing to convert <strong>the</strong>ir rights intocapital, given <strong>the</strong> right framew<strong>ork</strong>. The offeringof Ken Gen State Owned Corporation intendedto raise 8 billion Kenyan Schillings, but insteadraised 26 billion Schillings and drew three times<strong>the</strong> number of anticipated investors, many ofwho immediately tripled <strong>the</strong>ir money. As a resultinvestments in <strong>the</strong> stock market have grownsince 2002 from 50,000 investors to more than750,000 with much of <strong>the</strong> growth coming fromrural areas. The exchange’s total value jumpedfrom 1 billion Schillings to 12 billion Schillings,an amount that is predicted to grow following <strong>the</strong>biggest initial public offering in Kenyan historyof cell phone giant Safaricom. Natural resourcesrich countries such as Iraq, Venezuela, Chile,Peru, Congo and South Africa could easily empower<strong>the</strong>ir poor people by directly transferringproperty of <strong>the</strong>ir oil or minerals. 175103


Box 6 The Grameen BankStill <strong>the</strong> 7.06 million poor borrowers of <strong>the</strong> bank, ofwhich 97 per cent are women, own <strong>the</strong> most illustriousexample of a broadening of <strong>the</strong> asset base of <strong>the</strong> poorby shareholder strategies. Borrowers of Grameen Bankat present own 94 per cent of <strong>the</strong> total equity of <strong>the</strong>bank. The government owns <strong>the</strong> remaining 6 percent.The Grameen Bank is impressive in size and impact.It has 2,399 branches. It w<strong>ork</strong>s in 76,848 villages.Total staff is 22,169. 171 Loan recovery rate is 98.28per cent. 172 Grameen Bank finances 100 per cent of itsoutstanding loan from deposits of which over 60 percent come from <strong>the</strong> bank’s own borrowers. Many borrowersare moving ahead in businesses faster thano<strong>the</strong>rs. Grameen Bank provides larger loans, calledmicro-enterprise loans, <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>se fast moving members.There is no restriction on <strong>the</strong> loan size. So far 1,085,959members took micro-enterprise loans. A total of Tk23.42 billion (US$364.91 million) has been disbursedunder this category of loans. Average loan size is Tk21,566 (US$313), maximum loan taken so far is Tk 1.2million (US$19,897).Scholarships: Scholarships are given to <strong>the</strong> high per<strong>for</strong>mingchildren of Grameen borrowers, with priority ongirl children. Up to March 2007, scholarships amountingto US$550,000 have been awarded to 48,974children. During 2007, US$775,000 will be awardedto about 30,000 children, at various levels of education.By March 2007, 15,754 students received highereducation loans, of <strong>the</strong>m 14,739 at various universities;176 are studying in medical schools, 335 are studyingto become engineers, and 504 are studying in o<strong>the</strong>rprofessional institutions.Grameen Bank-Created Companies: A number ofcompanies were created by Grameen Bank, asseparate legal entities, to spin off some projectswithin Grameen Bank funded by donors. Donor fundstransferred to Grameen Fund were given as a loan fromGrameen Bank. 173 Grameen Bank created an internalfund called Social Advancement Fund (SAF) by imputinginterest on all <strong>the</strong> grant money it received fromvarious donors. SAF has been converted into a separatecompany to carry out its mandate to undertake socialadvance activities among <strong>the</strong> Grameen borrowers, suchas, education, health, technology, etc. 174Banking <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor. As often mentioned, <strong>the</strong>poor still make relatively little use of titles ascommercial credit. This is due to <strong>the</strong> perceivedrisks involved, as well as <strong>the</strong> difficulty or impossibilityof accessing credit. One ef<strong>for</strong>t to begin toaddress <strong>the</strong> problem associated with low levelsof banking activity among low-income earnersare Mzansi accounts, low-fee bank accounts designed<strong>for</strong> people w<strong>ork</strong>ing in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector.These accounts are offered by a group of SouthAfrican commercial banks in conjunction with <strong>the</strong>South African Post Office, and <strong>the</strong>y have beenquite successful. They allow people to become‘banked’, providing a means to establish a credithistory while risking less than <strong>the</strong> title to realproperty.Re<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>the</strong> Property System as anInstrument of Social PolicyProperty re<strong>for</strong>m with <strong>the</strong> poor in mind can be anefficient instrument of social policy with benefits <strong>for</strong>society at large. The state can foster <strong>the</strong> social fabricthrough property rights, such as in housing andneighbourhood development, low interest loans and<strong>the</strong> low priced sale of state land tied to conditionsof productivity and market based redistribution ofprivate land. Local political authorities can also see<strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m path towards more equitable propertyregimes as an opportunity to install participatoryprocesses and broader social dialogue in order topromote self-responsibility and social cohesion viaownership not only of property but also of <strong>the</strong> policyprocesses that establish property rules.104


Enhancing Access to Land and Real PropertyLandlessness is one of <strong>the</strong> greatest predictorsof poverty. Increasing security of propertyrights will have limited direct benefits <strong>for</strong> thosewho do not have any real assets at all. Whileland rental markets can, in rural areas, providean important avenue <strong>for</strong> greater land access by<strong>the</strong> poor and landless, <strong>the</strong>y need to be complementedby o<strong>the</strong>r measures to increase <strong>the</strong> assetendowment of <strong>the</strong> poor in situations where hugeinequalities persist.Create an Enabling Environment <strong>for</strong> Rental Markets.In most developing countries land and realproperty rental markets are underdeveloped. Butland and real property rentals are increasing. Productivity-enhancingrental transactions will notfully materialise or <strong>the</strong> poor may be excluded, ifleasehold tenure is insecure or restrictions constrainland leasing. 176 Replacing <strong>the</strong>m with policiesthat facilitate renting will improve access to land bythose remaining in <strong>the</strong> rural sector. 177 More robustand transparent guarantees should streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>position of slum dwellers in rental arrangementsand protect <strong>the</strong>m from arbitrary eviction.Legal Recognition of In<strong>for</strong>mal Settlements.Ensure <strong>the</strong> property rights of urban shantydwellersand rural state land squatters by granting<strong>the</strong>m title to <strong>the</strong>ir already occupied landsor suitable alternatives (see Section 5 of thisChapter), and introduce anti-eviction rights, limitationsof compulsory acquisitions, resettlementpolicies, adverse possession rights and family/group rights. 178<strong>Making</strong> Land Re<strong>for</strong>m Effective <strong>for</strong> IncreasingProductive Assets by <strong>the</strong> Poor. Land markets,or <strong>for</strong>malisation of existing land rights, are nota panacea <strong>for</strong> addressing structural inequalitieswhich reduce productivity of land use and holdback development. 179 To overcome <strong>the</strong> legacy ofBox 7 Mexico: <strong>the</strong> poor rely onpawnshops instead ofbanksMost Mexican citizens do not have access to bankingand only 13 percent hold mortgage debt. In <strong>the</strong>absence of financial institutions, <strong>the</strong> poor and lowermiddle classes rely on pawn shops. As movablecollateral valuation of consumer goods is difficult toestablish, <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong> collateral typically shortchanges<strong>the</strong> consumer. The annualised rate chargedby <strong>the</strong>se pawnshops ranges from 48 percentcharged by a non-profit pawnshop to 160 percent bya <strong>for</strong>-profit pawnshop. Some pawnshops will accepthouses as collateral (whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> underlying landis legally owned or not) in exchange <strong>for</strong> three yearloans.(La Crónica de Hoy, El top ten de la usura: la casade empeño Mister Money cobra 159.6 percent deinterés anual; Prenda Fácil, 146 percent; Montepío48 percent. Mexico City, October 9, 2006.)such inequality, ways of redistributing assets suchas land re<strong>for</strong>m will be needed. While <strong>the</strong> post-warexperiences of China, Japan, Korea and Taiwanshow that land re<strong>for</strong>m can improve equity andeconomic per<strong>for</strong>mance, many o<strong>the</strong>r cases whereland re<strong>for</strong>m could not be fully implemented oreven had negative consequences illustrate <strong>the</strong> difficultiesinvolved. Where redistributive land re<strong>for</strong>mis found to be more cost-effective in overcomingstructural inequalities than alternatives, it needs tobe complemented by access to managerial ability,technology, credit, and markets <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> new ownersto become competitive. A possible alternative, <strong>the</strong>impact of which needs to be explored more systematically,is <strong>the</strong> distribution of small house andgarden plots to <strong>the</strong> destitute to increase <strong>the</strong>ir foodsecurity and social status while at <strong>the</strong> same timeallowing <strong>the</strong>m to climb at least <strong>the</strong> first rung on<strong>the</strong> property rights ladder.Community-Based Land Re<strong>for</strong>m. As an alterna-105


tive to authoritative reallocation of land, community-basedland re<strong>for</strong>m projects provide fundsto groups of beneficiaries to purchase land. Whilebeing market-based, <strong>the</strong> idea behind such measuresis that land sale markets often do not moveland to those who have none or to small efficientproducers. The provision of funds is made availableunder <strong>the</strong> condition of a productive purposeand when land markets are sufficiently developed.The procedure is legally less complicatedand politically less sensitive than in compulsoryacquisition programmes. Legal re<strong>for</strong>m might berequired in <strong>the</strong> determination of legal personalityof associations or incorporations <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> groupseligible <strong>for</strong> funding, but it is probably best to letbeneficiaries experiment with a number of possibleassociational <strong>for</strong>ms. Legal conditionality regarding<strong>the</strong> groups of beneficiaries does, however,leave room <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> pursuit of o<strong>the</strong>r social purposes.In Andhra Pradesh, <strong>for</strong> instance, purchasedland is given in <strong>the</strong> name of women only. 180Limit Administrative Controls on Sales. Often<strong>the</strong>re is little justification <strong>for</strong> policy measures torestrict land sales which drive land sales undergroundand undermine access to <strong>for</strong>mal credit.If <strong>the</strong>re is an issue of asymmetries in power, accessto insurance, and in<strong>for</strong>mation leading toundesirable land market outcomes or speculativeland accumulation, safety nets and o<strong>the</strong>r measures,including ways of redistributing land, willbe more appropriate to prevent distress sales.Moreover, land taxes with temporal and user-orientedconditionality can curb speculative demandand encourage better land use, while providingrevenue <strong>for</strong> local governments. 181Make benefits from past land re<strong>for</strong>m permanent:There are also many situations where those whohave received land rights in <strong>the</strong> past are unableto enjoy <strong>the</strong> full benefits because <strong>the</strong>y have notreceived full ownership rights or because transferabilityof <strong>the</strong>ir rights was restricted. As secondgeneration problems can threaten to undermineearlier successes, it will be important to providefull ownership rights to those affected, if needbe by identifying innovative approaches — e.g.,a credit-financed purchase of residual ownershiprights by one of <strong>the</strong> parties involved.The Benefi cial Effects of Property RelatedEducation and Relevant In<strong>for</strong>mation.Households’ awareness and in<strong>for</strong>mation ofrights has a significant and large impacton <strong>the</strong> positive outcomes of property regimes. 182There is evidence of a strong and positive relationshipbetween households’ objective knowledgeof <strong>the</strong> law and land-related investmentsand, through such investments, on productivityand land values. The fact that often only a minorityof land users is aware of relevant legal provisionsimplies that <strong>the</strong> lion’s share of <strong>the</strong> associatedproductivity gains remains to be realised.Given <strong>the</strong>ir low cost, especially if compared toef<strong>for</strong>ts to demarcate lands, programmes to disseminate<strong>the</strong> law and make households awareof <strong>the</strong>ir rights could thus have very high returnsand should accompany any property rights re<strong>for</strong>mpolicy. Scientific evidence as well as grass-rootsconsultations by <strong>the</strong> Commission on Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor demonstrates that socialpolicy should promote legal literacy and proceduralassistance to close <strong>the</strong> discrepancy betweenlegal provisions and ground realities, and to helpthose who are given rights through <strong>the</strong> law to exercise<strong>the</strong>m. 183Promoting Access to HousingUrban Infrastructure projects, housing and propertyrights creation can be pursued toge<strong>the</strong>r andare mutually rein<strong>for</strong>cing. 184 As a sector, housingis a local economic activity, generating income,106


Box 8 Example of Singapore:public housing aseconomic stimulantSingapore’s experience has shown that public housingconstruction expenditure can have a multipliereffect that stimulates <strong>the</strong> economy and contributesemployment growth in <strong>the</strong> building and constructionindustry. The ratio of construction to <strong>the</strong> country’sGDP has increased both absolutely and relativelyover <strong>the</strong> past three decades, about 40 percent ofGDP. The construction industry has a labour absorptioncapacity <strong>for</strong> skilled and unskilled w<strong>ork</strong>ers.Estimates indicate that <strong>the</strong> construction of oneunit of public housing at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> Housingand Development Board’s (HDB) first building programme(1960-65) would generate employment <strong>for</strong>a person <strong>for</strong> nine months directly at <strong>the</strong> constructionsite, while a HDB building programme of 10,000units per year would create 15,000 jobs. In additionwith <strong>the</strong> policy of reserving about 10 percent of newtown land <strong>for</strong> industrial development public housinginvestment has generated a significant numberof new jobs near <strong>the</strong> homes of new town residents,especially <strong>for</strong> women who o<strong>the</strong>rwise might not haveentered <strong>the</strong> labour <strong>for</strong>ce. Over <strong>the</strong> 10-year period1970-80 female participation rates increased from29.5 percent to 44.3 percent. Thus, housing shouldnot be viewed simply as a means of resolving shelterproblems but also as a potentially leading sector ofgrowth in national economy. Source: Yuen 2002.employing local labour, and re-circulating incomeinto <strong>the</strong> local economy. Housing production producesspill over effects such as <strong>the</strong> developmentof skilled labour, and production of householdgoods. 185 Fur<strong>the</strong>r, from a macroeconomic perspective,<strong>the</strong> housing sector has a broad impacton economic per<strong>for</strong>mance affecting prices, investmentand employment, streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong>financial sector and fiscal budget, and having apervasive impact on <strong>the</strong> economy. 186Access to Housing as a Poverty Alleviation Strategy.187 Decent and safe housing provides a stableplace <strong>for</strong> family activities; it enables <strong>the</strong> storage,preservation, and preparation of food; it is a fixedlocation <strong>for</strong> delivery of services such as waterand collection of household refuse <strong>for</strong> orderlydisposal; and, it serves as a protected place toguard possessions from environmental damage or<strong>the</strong>ft. 188 Loss of housing, tragic anywhere, can becatastrophic in <strong>the</strong> developing world. 189 Housingstability is a particularly important poverty alleviationstrategy <strong>for</strong> women. In developing economies<strong>the</strong> home not only serves as shelter but alsois frequently a place <strong>for</strong> business.Housing Finance. Analysis by UN-Habitat revealsthat <strong>the</strong> global housing needs cannot be met byaid or state subsidies alone. Meeting <strong>the</strong> housingneeds of <strong>the</strong> world’s poor will require economicgrowth (job and income generation) and housingfinance. However, stimulating housing productionand catalysing financial markets have o<strong>the</strong>r positiveeffects, that go beyond <strong>the</strong> development of <strong>the</strong>housing itself. In markets where financial institutionsare not active because a market is untested,governments can leverage private sector financingby providing credit enhancement to support borrowers,developers or lenders; using subsidies judiciouslyto leverage financing, assuring transparency;and facilitating in<strong>for</strong>mation. There are manymodels of specialized programs that provide incentivesto financial institutions to lend to <strong>the</strong> poor aswell as to those who serve <strong>the</strong>m. The governmentcan play a catalytic role in bringing toge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>private sector and o<strong>the</strong>r institutions. 190Despite <strong>the</strong> obvious importance of housing productionand its reliance on finance, <strong>the</strong> existingfinancing instruments to address <strong>the</strong> shelter needsof <strong>the</strong> poor are at a nascent stage. Existing instrumentsdo not fully respond to <strong>the</strong> reality of povertyor <strong>the</strong> need. 191 To meet <strong>the</strong> need, many countriesadopt housing policies, known as ‘filtering’ strate-107


Box 9 Singapore: importanceof w<strong>ork</strong>ers’ CentralProvident FundUnder <strong>the</strong> scheme first instituted in 1955, employeesin Singapore are required by law to save a proportionof <strong>the</strong>ir monthly income in a central providentfund (CPF) account. Employers also make monthlycontributions to <strong>the</strong>ir employees’ CPF account. Muchof <strong>the</strong>se savings are invested in government securities,providing a cheap and ready source of financeto <strong>the</strong> government <strong>for</strong> public housing constructionand national capital <strong>for</strong>mation. They also provide asource of mortgage financing at <strong>the</strong> individual levelto help home buyers meet <strong>the</strong>ir mortgage paymentswithout <strong>the</strong> need to dip into <strong>the</strong>ir cash reserves. For<strong>the</strong> average w<strong>ork</strong>er <strong>the</strong> monthly repayment <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>fl at is less than half of <strong>the</strong> CPF savings deposit.Sources: Yuen 2002, 2005.gies. 192 However, a key limitation of a mortgagebasedfiltering strategy is that it has a long timehorizon at best; and, a market-based filteringstrategy that is not matched with housing policiestargeted to <strong>the</strong> poor, will result in inequalities andleave <strong>the</strong> poor behind.Some countries have been extensively involved insetting housing goals and directly financing housing.Singapore, once characterised by vast squattersettlements, established a Housing and DevelopmentBoard (HDB) to finance and subsidisehousing developed by <strong>the</strong> state but constructedby <strong>the</strong> private sector and <strong>the</strong>n sold to homebuyers.Over 85 percent of Singaporeans live ingovernment-built housing. Singapore has emphasiseda homeownership strategy that has playeda key part in raising residents’ sense of belongingto <strong>the</strong> new living environment.There are also many examples of developing nationscommitted to meet <strong>the</strong>ir housing challengesand testing and developing a broad variety ofhousing policies. South Africa quickly startedoff with an impressive array of housing policyresponses, such as housing plans, fixed interestloan products, micro-loan financing, a securitisationconduit, and partnerships with financialinstitutions. The country is still in <strong>the</strong> process ofexperimentation and evaluation, but <strong>the</strong> commitmentto its housing sector is clear. 193Public Private PartnershipsSeveral <strong>for</strong>ms of public private partnerships(PPPs) were developed in <strong>the</strong> last two decadeswith built-in provisions of housing <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>poor. This period saw <strong>the</strong> economies of severaldeveloping countries booming and globalising,with a direct impact on cities like Sao Paolo,Mumbai, Delhi, Seoul, Kuala Lumpur, Manila andJakarta. Economic opportunities created a hugedemand <strong>for</strong> space <strong>for</strong> businesses and housing, inturn creating business opportunities <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> realestate sector, <strong>for</strong> which it needed land in primelocations and land with trunk services in peripheralareas, both of which were scarce. The sameeconomic opportunities meant a growing populationof <strong>the</strong> poor who could af<strong>for</strong>d only in<strong>for</strong>malaccess to space in <strong>the</strong> city, with all its legal andenvironmental insecurities. Pressures placedupon city development institutions, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e,gave birth to public-private partnerships as oneapproach to solving problems affecting both <strong>the</strong>real estate sector and <strong>the</strong> poor.Successful PPPs from which <strong>the</strong> poor have benefitedhave tended to rely on instruments of <strong>the</strong>state <strong>for</strong> trunk infrastructure that would ensureadequate timing of project development, and <strong>for</strong>en<strong>for</strong>cement of new regulations and laws. Thereare several examples where a combination of <strong>the</strong>seinstruments has been used to ensure legal/<strong>for</strong>malaccess to land and housing <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor. GuidedLand Development has been implemented in <strong>the</strong>108


Box 10 Slum upgradinginitiative in Dali<strong>for</strong>t,SenegalUpgrading of slums in Dali<strong>for</strong>t has provided dwellers<strong>the</strong>re with new opportunities and better livingenvironment. A <strong>for</strong>mal land title has been granted tomore than 500 head of households including womenand <strong>the</strong>ir houses have been connected to <strong>the</strong> basicservices. Because of its proximity to <strong>the</strong> city centre,rent and land price have steadily risen, and <strong>the</strong>settlement has seen rapid development of high-risehousing of good quality. Noticeable growth of neweconomic activities favoured by land security andmicrocredit facilities that have helped slum dwellersaccess start-up funding to initiate income generatingactivities that contributed to <strong>the</strong>ir economicempowerment. Source: Diop 2007.periphery of cities like Seoul, Jakarta, Chennai,and Delhi, under conditions obliging private landownersto provide a certain percentage of smallplots which poor families can af<strong>for</strong>d. 194Transfer of Development Rights (TDR) is an effectiveinstrument applied in such projects to generatelow income housing on high value city landthrough <strong>the</strong> participation of private landownersand developers. Private landowners, or developerswilling to build houses <strong>for</strong> existing in<strong>for</strong>maldwellers, are given <strong>the</strong> right to build more than<strong>the</strong> permissible floor space index or floor arearatio specified in zoning regulations <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> plot.If possible, <strong>the</strong>y can build additional space on<strong>the</strong> same plot or be allowed to transfer <strong>the</strong> developmentright to o<strong>the</strong>r plots in specified zones. 195TDR w<strong>ork</strong>s where <strong>the</strong>re is a high premium onland and where <strong>the</strong> permissible density is highenough to leave surplus land after building lowincomehousing.Government as intermediary and facilitator betweenowners and low-income occupiers. In <strong>the</strong>case of Land Sharing as used extensively in <strong>the</strong>Indian city of Hyderabad and to some extent inBangkok, Thailand, <strong>the</strong> Municipal Corporation ofHyderabad and <strong>the</strong> national Housing Authorityof Thailand largely play <strong>the</strong> role of intermediaries.Government authorities in those places helpto negotiate deals between owners of <strong>the</strong> landand its low-income occupiers. Once agreement isreached to share <strong>the</strong> land, <strong>the</strong> governments <strong>the</strong>nhelp <strong>the</strong> occupants to gain access to finance <strong>for</strong>rebuilding housing in <strong>the</strong> portion of land <strong>the</strong>y areto occupy under <strong>the</strong> shared arrangement. The fee<strong>for</strong> registering <strong>the</strong> new ownership and transfer ofproperty is exempted by <strong>the</strong> government. 196 Thearrangement w<strong>ork</strong>s in situations where <strong>the</strong> originallandowners have little hope of recovering <strong>the</strong>iroccupied property without prolonged litigation,and where getting even a part of <strong>the</strong> land backhas major advantages.Fostering Citizenship and Legal Empowermentthrough Consultation, In<strong>for</strong>mation andParticipatory Property Re<strong>for</strong>mOffering public education and legal aid regardingmarket structures to <strong>the</strong> poor is of critical importance,o<strong>the</strong>rwise <strong>the</strong> effectiveness <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor of<strong>the</strong> above mentioned measures of legal re<strong>for</strong>m,governance re<strong>for</strong>m and market development canbe nullified. Multiple consultations, involvement ofsocial organisations in <strong>the</strong> contacting of propertyholders, well-publicised displays and provision ofmaterials to communities all contribute to satisfactionand improved efficiency of property re<strong>for</strong>m.In particular, active communication toward andparticipation by civil society are important to ensure<strong>the</strong> quality of systemic change in <strong>the</strong> propertyrights regime.These mechanisms allow beneficiaries to havein<strong>for</strong>mation about <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m’s framew<strong>ork</strong>, strategies,implementation and targets as well as to109


Box 11 Peru regularises <strong>the</strong> process of titling propertywithin settlementsTo initiate <strong>the</strong> regularisation process of property in eachsettlement, an in<strong>for</strong>mational assembly was held toexplain details of <strong>the</strong> procedure, obtain approval of <strong>the</strong>assembly. Each assembly was required to designate itsown representatives. At this stage, problems such asmultiple or questionable leadership groups were resolved.These problems generally arose when <strong>the</strong>re wasevidence of lack of representation or when those havingdeveloped clientelistic links with municipal authoritiesassumed questionable leadership. The strategyemployed by Peru’s Commission <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Formalisationof In<strong>for</strong>mal Property (COFOPRI) in breaking this patternwas to establish a direct link with <strong>the</strong> settler assemblies<strong>the</strong>mselves. The assembly made it possible <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> majority of <strong>the</strong> settlers to link directly with COFOPRIand to decide <strong>the</strong> best way to initiate <strong>the</strong> titling processand exercise <strong>the</strong>ir representation. To this end, 3,500in<strong>for</strong>mative assemblies were held in 3,500 settlementsbetween 1996 and 2000.Between 1996 and 2001, some 2,274 settlements wereregularised in all of Peru, which represented one milliontitled families. The 6,000 in<strong>for</strong>mative and preparatoryassemblies held in this period are <strong>the</strong> clearest proofof <strong>the</strong> high level of citizen participation in <strong>the</strong> process.The meetings in<strong>for</strong>med settlers of <strong>the</strong> kind of documentationneeded by officials charged with creating <strong>the</strong> listof legal occupants. The officials would visit <strong>the</strong> homesof settlers to explain how conflicts and <strong>the</strong> lack of evidentiarydocuments might be resolved.To promote responsibility among officials in charge oftitling services, <strong>the</strong> parties responsible <strong>for</strong> deliveringservices to each settlement were clearly identified, soresidents knew which officials were in charge. Unlike<strong>the</strong> previous titling process, when only certain directorshad access to in<strong>for</strong>mation such as changes in titlingprocedures and <strong>the</strong> identity of <strong>the</strong> officials responsible,COFOPRI guaranteed <strong>the</strong> right of any person to receivein<strong>for</strong>mation about <strong>the</strong> titling process and to know <strong>the</strong>officials in charge. Studies developed in 2000 to evaluate<strong>the</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance of <strong>the</strong> Peruvian project confirmedthat <strong>the</strong>se participatory mechanisms raised <strong>the</strong> communitysupport and satisfaction with <strong>the</strong> project.Source: Mosquiera, 2007.participate in specific stages of <strong>the</strong> planningand implementation of re<strong>for</strong>m. They expand <strong>the</strong>beneficiaries’ capacity to participate, negotiate,influence, control and hold accountable <strong>the</strong>public institutions in charge of property rightsre<strong>for</strong>m and administration. On a broader scale,such measures integrate <strong>the</strong> positive elements ofproperty rules, such as allocation of responsibilityand liability with <strong>the</strong> fostering of citizenship andsocial cohesion. 197Recommendations <strong>for</strong> Policy Designand SequencingIt is advisable to integrate action projects regarding<strong>the</strong> four building blocks of <strong>the</strong> propertysystem into a design that pays attention to additionalelements:1. Build-in Research and Policy Analysis as wellas Piloting and Evaluation Schemes ahead ofFull-scale Implementation. A policy projectwith little policy analysis and research tocompare methodologies, prioritise areas andspecial measures, pilot innovations or evaluateitself will suffer from a slow institutionallearning process and will risk to detect dysfunctionslate. The long-term sustainabilityof property re<strong>for</strong>ms must be addressed early,alongside with potential <strong>for</strong> conflicts causedby re<strong>for</strong>m processes.110


2. Pay Attention to Sequencing. The contentand sequence of a set of re<strong>for</strong>m actions and<strong>the</strong> setting of priorities will have to be left tocontext-based analysis in national and localsettings. Formally however, it is important topoint to <strong>the</strong> fact that success of <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms ineach of <strong>the</strong> four building blocks of <strong>the</strong> propertysystem will depend not only on <strong>the</strong> qualityof <strong>the</strong> individual measures taken but on <strong>the</strong>sequence in which <strong>the</strong>y are taken. Getting <strong>the</strong>phasing right is as important as <strong>the</strong> content of<strong>the</strong> individual measures. 1983. Issues of Sovereignty and Territorial Autonomy,e.g. regarding indigenous people, must be assessedand tackled prior to re<strong>for</strong>m of propertyrights regimes, or restitution or privatisation insensitive areas. O<strong>the</strong>rwise <strong>the</strong> envisioned processwill be affected negatively, delayed or evennullified. 1994. On-<strong>the</strong>-Ground Assessments. Even if re<strong>for</strong>mmeasures are carried out diligently <strong>the</strong>y maybe perceived as interventionist and top-downoriented by <strong>the</strong> poor. Property rights re<strong>for</strong>mprogrammes have often been successful wherealso based on <strong>the</strong> ground assessment of ownershipand family relations. Differences infamily and community structures and spatialorganisation have to be identified at <strong>the</strong> fieldlevel (in<strong>for</strong>mal marriages, de-facto headships,spontaneous organisation of public spaces,etc). In most contexts this planning measurefacilitates <strong>the</strong> collection of reliable data aboutpossessions and functioning customs, it gives<strong>the</strong> poor a sense of being taken seriously during<strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m process, produces transparency in<strong>the</strong> property rights’ definition processes, makesofficials more accountable to <strong>the</strong> process, contributesto <strong>the</strong> reduction of conflicts amongbeneficiaries, and might even create bottom-uppressure <strong>for</strong> more legal and regulatory re<strong>for</strong>ms.5. The Art of <strong>the</strong> Long Breath. A full scale re<strong>for</strong>m,including legal re<strong>for</strong>m and parallel interventionsin all four building blocks of <strong>the</strong> propertyrights system, cannot be carried out within <strong>the</strong>normal cycle of democratic elections and hasto be sustained over several legislatures. Someindividual re<strong>for</strong>m benefits might be visiblerapidly, but sustained beneficial effects onlytake hold if property rights re<strong>for</strong>m is sustainedand carried out over a long period of time. On<strong>the</strong> macro level, beneficial effects of propertyrights re<strong>for</strong>m will take hold over 10-15 years.Given this need <strong>for</strong> long breath, enlightenedauthoritarian regimes seem to have an easiertask in property re<strong>for</strong>m than emerging ordeficient democracies. However, <strong>the</strong>re areseveral ways in which property rights re<strong>for</strong>mcan be sustained over <strong>the</strong> normal life cycle ofa democratic government. One possibility isto promote re<strong>for</strong>ms with broad support fromseveral parties and to make property re<strong>for</strong>m ageneral interest grounded in <strong>the</strong> constitution.In order to overcome <strong>for</strong>midable oppositionfrom powerful social actors against propertyre<strong>for</strong>m, broad popular demand <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m fromcivil society and <strong>the</strong> private sector and strongcoalitions of change are needed. Need assessment,awareness and in<strong>for</strong>mation campaignsamong civil society and grass-roots movementsneed to be fostered to marginalize <strong>the</strong>powerful gatekeepers of <strong>the</strong> status quo of vastextra-legality. This ought to be conceived asa multi-stakeholder ef<strong>for</strong>t including media,business groups and associations of <strong>the</strong> poor,academia, and government agencies favourableto change.111


What can Donor Countries andMultilateralism do <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Promotionof Property Rights of <strong>the</strong> Global Poor?The establishment of fully functional propertysystems and pro-poor re<strong>for</strong>m is first and <strong>for</strong>emosta national and local issue. It demands <strong>the</strong> renegotiationof institutional, legal and social relationsat national and local levels. Assisting countriesand multilateral organisations are obligatednot to disrupt ongoing processes of renegotiation.Fur<strong>the</strong>r ef<strong>for</strong>ts of donor countries are required todesign <strong>the</strong>ir own laws so that <strong>the</strong>y do not aggravate<strong>the</strong> problems of <strong>the</strong> world’s poorest. Donorcountries, <strong>for</strong> example, need to deny giving safehaven to bank deposits by elites having lootedresources from <strong>the</strong> world’s poorest societies, and<strong>the</strong>y should actively w<strong>ork</strong> to prevent payment ofdomestic company bribes to public officials ofdeveloping countries. 200 Some advocate <strong>for</strong> anactive role of international organisations in domesticgovernance, circumventing domestic elitesand institutionalising <strong>the</strong> necessary governancere<strong>for</strong>ms. 201 To date, <strong>the</strong>re is little evidence tosuggest that it can make a noticeable difference.A better option is to make re<strong>for</strong>ms more sustainableby coordinating and supporting broad re<strong>for</strong>mmeasures multilaterally. Concern <strong>for</strong> longer-termendurance of re<strong>for</strong>ms is an important consideration,given that <strong>the</strong> concerns of individual governmentsmay be short-lived due to <strong>the</strong> fact that<strong>the</strong>y are limited to short cycles of legislation. Thisshould help to ensure that <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms will endureover <strong>the</strong> long term, something that individualgovernments, limited to short cycles of legislation,may not normally be able to accomplish.A System of Multilateral Charters. One of <strong>the</strong>most important development economists hasproposed a system of charters to legally empower<strong>the</strong> world’s poor. The charters would set minimumstandards <strong>for</strong> natural resource revenues to states,<strong>for</strong> checks and balances in governance, budgettransparency, post conflict management, and <strong>for</strong>investment. 202 Property rights are present anddeserve central attention in all <strong>the</strong>se charters,since <strong>the</strong>y could be decisive in making systemicproperty re<strong>for</strong>m sustainable.The charter <strong>for</strong> natural resource revenue, <strong>for</strong>example, would set minimum standards oftransparency and fair competition <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> auctioningof extraction rights, diminish <strong>the</strong> price risk<strong>for</strong> government of poor countries, honestly brokerin<strong>for</strong>mation about money flows to government byextraction companies, and set standards <strong>for</strong> publicexpenditure of natural resource revenue — channellingit to domestic market development andcitizen-owned equity funds. The charter <strong>for</strong> checksand balances would set limits to government and/or private monopolies in <strong>the</strong> ownership and controlof media companies and regulate financing andspending in election campaigns. The charter <strong>for</strong>budget transparency would commit governmentsto <strong>the</strong> monthly publication of allocation of assetsto government institutions in order to allow scrutinyfrom below and install intergovernmental peerreview mechanisms. The charter <strong>for</strong> post-conflictsituations would commit external security andlegal en<strong>for</strong>cement <strong>for</strong>ces <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> long haul, set uptransparent budgetary processes and participatorygovernment, regulate property restitution and <strong>the</strong>w<strong>ork</strong> reconciliation commissions. The investmentcharter would establish credibility by precludinggovernments from strategies of confiscation andlimit extreme manipulation of exchange rates, prices,and public utility charges. Instead of pushingre<strong>for</strong>m processes individually, like minded countriesmight also agree on some essential points ofa property systems re<strong>for</strong>m listed in this report andcommit to such re<strong>for</strong>m in a charter, complementing<strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r charters needed to link <strong>the</strong> world’smost poor to <strong>the</strong> chains of value addition.112


Foster Coalitions of Change in Favour of EquitableProperty Systems. Donors and international organisationscan engage with domestic groups — suchas businesses, NGOs and grassroots movements ofpeasants and small-business owners — and enlist<strong>the</strong>ir support <strong>for</strong> property rights re<strong>for</strong>ms in contactwith governments. Depending on <strong>the</strong> circumstances,fostering coalitions of change by such practicesmay potentially bear fruit. Success requireslong-term commitment by <strong>the</strong> parties, a stronglocal ownership, wide stakeholder participationand good local management capacity. Donorcountries and multilateral institutions have animportant subsidiary role to play in areas of transnationalin<strong>for</strong>mation ga<strong>the</strong>ring and distribution,education, and technical assistance. Multilateralorganisations have an important role to playin making <strong>the</strong> engagements of donor countriesmore coherent and coordinated and in providingstandards <strong>for</strong> intergovernmental peer review.Although <strong>the</strong>re is now considerable awarenessof <strong>the</strong> importance of property rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor,failure to appreciate <strong>the</strong> historical roots, complexity,and political nature of <strong>the</strong> underlying issuescan give rise to recommendations that maynot only fail to do justice to <strong>the</strong> topic but couldalso prove to be unsustainable.Capacity Building and Technical Assistance.Given <strong>the</strong> context-specificity and politicallysensitive nature of property issues and to makeservices in this area accessible to a majority of<strong>the</strong> population, <strong>the</strong>re is a significant need <strong>for</strong>building capacity on both <strong>the</strong> technical andanalytical levels within <strong>the</strong> public sector as wellas among o<strong>the</strong>r agents who can be mobilised. Inthis domain, <strong>the</strong> international community anddonor countries can provide trans-governmentalor multilaterally coordinated assistance in capacitybuilding leading to greater sustainabilityof re<strong>for</strong>m programmes.Seed-financing of Property Re<strong>for</strong>m. Functionalproperty systems are self-sustainable. Longstanding injection of aid from abroad would beseen as harmful to this goal or a symptom ofsystemic inadequacy. However, in <strong>the</strong> early stages,and depending on <strong>the</strong> context, many of <strong>the</strong>above mentioned re<strong>for</strong>ms might be triggered bya combination of technical assistance and seedfinancingfrom abroad. Such projects should beaccompanied by clear terms of reference as to<strong>the</strong> timetable and phases on <strong>the</strong> path to selfsustainability.Cross-country Land Policy Indicators. Although<strong>the</strong> importance is widely recognised, it is oftendifficult to integrate land rights into policy dialogueor to demonstrate <strong>the</strong> seriousness of anissue due to <strong>the</strong> lack of comparable indicators.Experience in o<strong>the</strong>r sectors has shown that defininga simple set of indicators, some of whichcould be generated by <strong>the</strong> land administrationsystem on a routine basis, could make it mucheasier to steer <strong>the</strong> policy dialogue towards criticalissues and at <strong>the</strong> same time to measureprogress over time. Such indicators should include:(1) coverage and accessibility of <strong>the</strong> system,potential and actual; (2) cost-effectivenessof service provision; (3) extent to which governmentholds or acquires land rights and <strong>the</strong> wayin which <strong>the</strong>y are exercised, and (4) ways toaccess property through market and non-marketchannels.Ranking Systems of Property Rights Af<strong>for</strong>ded toWomen. In <strong>the</strong> multilateral sphere, one possibleapproach to addressing <strong>the</strong> problem of discriminationof women in property matters would be to<strong>for</strong>mulate a rigorous ranking system of propertyrights protection af<strong>for</strong>ded to women. Such anindex/ranking may focus attention on how differentcountries score in terms of en<strong>for</strong>cement,protection, scope and depth of rights. Ranking113


ef<strong>for</strong>ts have proved useful in <strong>the</strong> ‘doing business’environment. Property rights are a componentof World Bank rankings, but <strong>the</strong> propertyrights’ components are not gender-specific. Aseparate ranking may draw more attention to <strong>the</strong>issue and prompt improvement in <strong>the</strong> propertyrightsenvironment <strong>for</strong> women.6. Concluding MessageThe relevance of fair access to property rightsgoes way beyond <strong>the</strong>ir role as economic assets.Secure and accessible property rights provide asense of identity, dignity, and belonging to peopleof very different economic means. They createreliable ties of rights and obligations among communitymembers as well as a system of mutualrecognition of rights and responsibilities beyond<strong>the</strong> local community. For many poor individualsand <strong>the</strong> communities in which <strong>the</strong>y live, <strong>the</strong>relationship with property is more than just anaggregate of occupied and used plots. It is <strong>the</strong>very expression of a way of life, and one that <strong>the</strong>yshould have <strong>the</strong> opportunity to improve by virtueof <strong>the</strong>ir own ef<strong>for</strong>ts.114


Chapter 2 EndnotesUniversal Declaration of Human Rights, Article 17, Provisions (1) and(2). Securing agreement on this <strong>for</strong>mulation required omitting <strong>the</strong> wordprivate be<strong>for</strong>e property. See Glendon 2001: 182-3.2 See Cheneval 2006.3 See Locke 1988; Wheeler 1980.4 See Cavallar 2002. This report understands private property rightsas a spectrum of ownership and usufruct rights that are not held by <strong>the</strong>state and allocated to a an individual bearer or a corporate group ofbearers. In customary as well as advanced capitalist systems, privateproperty rights can be owned individually and in common by individualand corporative legal persons. The w<strong>ork</strong>ing group <strong>for</strong> this Chapter isaware that this understanding runs contrary to a notion restricting <strong>the</strong>use of <strong>the</strong> term ‘private property’ to individual freehold.5 Sachs (2006: 18) estimates that 2.5 billion people currently live inpoverty in developing countries.6 These countries were Dominica, Grenada, Samoa, St. Lucia and St.Vincent and <strong>the</strong> Grenadines, all tiny island states in which issues ofproperty rights are signifi cantly smaller in scale than those in muchlarger countries. Of <strong>the</strong> 76 countries measured within <strong>the</strong> CPIA, onlySamoa scored an aggregate 4 out of 6 over <strong>the</strong> total 16 governanceindicators. 2005 IDA Resource Allocation Index, Available at www.worldbank.org.7 World Bank, CPIA 2005 Assessment Questionnaire: 33, available atwww.worldbank.org.8 United Nations 1980.9 Woolf 1938.10 IFAD 2001: 86.11 Nielsen 2006: 204-219.12 Ravna 2006: 77.13 Estimates by <strong>the</strong> UN Human Settlements Program indicate that over<strong>the</strong> next 25 years this fi gure will increase by more than 2 billion people.14 Sachs 2006: 27.15 Building on a body of recent literature, <strong>the</strong> 2005 IFAD report onrural development defi nes an asset (also called ‘capital’, ‘stock’, or ‘endowment’)as ‘anything that can be used, without being used up, toincrease regular returns above receipts from labour, whe<strong>the</strong>r hired orself-employed, and thus enhance producers’ income of consumers’ welfare.Typical assets are land, wells, cattle, tools, houses, shares, skills,health and roads.’16 de Soto 2000.17 Detailed in Alden Wily and Mbaya 2001.18 Alden Wily and Mbaya 2001.19 Even in countries where government may be relied upon to stay within<strong>the</strong> boundaries of <strong>the</strong> law, overly flexible terminology leads to opportunity<strong>for</strong> public purpose to turn into private purpose as recent cases in <strong>the</strong> USSupreme Court illustrate. This is even more important <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> global poorwho often live where <strong>the</strong>re is limited residual faith in governments keepingto <strong>the</strong> spirit of <strong>the</strong> law.20 Hart 1961.21 European Commission 2007: 4.22 Mosqueira 2007: 7.23 IFAD 2001: 88.24 IFAD 2001: 88.25 UN-HABITAT 2005a: 107.26 CLEP In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses India: 10.27 See Collier 2007: 140-146.28 See Garcia-Bolivar 2007.29 See Prahalda 2005: 87-88.30 See Mendoza 2006: 17.31 South African Institute of International Affairs 2005.32 USAID 2007 terms it <strong>the</strong> ‘substantive dimensions of legal empowerment’.33 Terminology is never unifi ed. Defi nitional guidance, also beyond Africa,is given in: Land Tenure Lexicon 2000.34 See Cotula 2007.35 See World Development Report 2002: 9.36 Population Reference Bureau 2005.37 UN-HABITAT 2005b: Chapter 1.38 Alden Wily 2006c: 1739 FAO 2007.40 This has been largely <strong>the</strong> case <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> thirty or so wars of <strong>the</strong> lastseveral decades from Cambodia to Chile, Bosnia to Zimbabwe, Afghanistanto Peru. It has been uni<strong>for</strong>mly <strong>the</strong> case in <strong>the</strong> region where civil warshave been most numerous over <strong>the</strong> last two decades, Sub-Saharan Africa.(Richards 2005; Currey 2004)41 Sudan Comprehensive Peace Agreement, January 2005 and InterimNational Constitution, Sudan, 2005. Alden Wily 2007.42 Hurwitz et al. 200543 The land and product values of <strong>for</strong>est resources is immense, mildlyindicative in only <strong>the</strong> recorded global timber trading values of US$354billion in 2000, <strong>the</strong> US$5.56 trillion import value of non-timber <strong>for</strong>estproducts in 2002 (from brazil nuts to gum arabica) and <strong>the</strong> already millionsof dollars being expended that year in trading carbon credits from<strong>for</strong>est stocks. FAO 2005.44 Their share of income capture from commercial logging and paperproduction <strong>for</strong> example has been minimal to non-existent to date (e.g.Liberia, Papua New Guinea, Nepal, Brazil). FAO 2005; Colchester et al.2001.45 Conditions are particularly severe in Africa, <strong>the</strong> Middle East andSouth Asia. See World Bank 2004a: 1.46 See Hodgson 2004.47 United Nations 1980: 8. This old fi gure is not based on rigorousmeasurement. In some more recent studies even lower percentages areindicated. See FAO 1999. Women’s right to land and natural resources:some implications <strong>for</strong> a human-rights based approach. SD Dimensions115


(on fi le at FAO: http://www.fao.org/sd/LTdirect/LTan0025.htm).48 Nielsen 2006: 206; CLEP Uganda: 21, CLEP Indonesia, CLEP Philippines,CLEP Sri Lanka: 13.49 Ann Whitehead and Dzodzi Tsikata 2003: 77.50 Izumi 2007.51 Agarwal 1994.52 ICRW 2005: 3.53 Quisumbing and Maluccio 2000.54 Not always, <strong>for</strong> example, Inuit are 85 percent of <strong>the</strong> semi-autonomousGreenland region of Denmark. Indigenous people represent half or morecitizens of Guatemala, Peru and especially Bolivia.55 In 1972 <strong>the</strong> UN W<strong>ork</strong>ing Group on Indigenous Populations accepteda defi nition, amended in 1983 and 1986. The ILO Convention No. 169 in1989 accepted a broader defi nition, embodied in <strong>the</strong> UN Declaration on<strong>the</strong> Rights of Indigenous Peoples.56 There are people in o<strong>the</strong>r regions regulating <strong>the</strong>ir land relationsthrough indigenous norms. They are mainly members of indigenous minorities,such as Native Americans in North America, Sami in <strong>the</strong> nor<strong>the</strong>rnpolar areas of Europe and Russia and native peoples of Australiaand New Zealand. They are excluded here mainly because comparativelyextremely few of <strong>the</strong>ir number are defi nitively ‘poor’.57 Kaelin 2006: 175.58 An estimated 25 million persons have been displaced by armedconfl ict in more than 40 countries. In Africa, <strong>the</strong> number of IDPs reaches13.2 million, in Central and South America 3.7 million, in Asia 3.3 million,in Europe 3 million, and in <strong>the</strong> Middle East 2.1 million. In 2004, <strong>the</strong>largest internal displacement situations were Sudan (5-6 million IDPs),Colombia (2 - 3 million), DRC (2.3 million), Uganda (up to 2 million),and Iraq (over 1 million). Sudan, Uganda, Colombia, Iraq, Somalia, andNepal were <strong>the</strong> scene of major new displacement during <strong>the</strong> same year,whereas DRC, Angola, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Sudan, Liberia, Burundi, and CentralAfrican Republic saw major return movements. (Norwegian RefugeeCouncil, Global IDP Project, Internal Displacement — Global Overviewof Trends and Developments in 2004, Geneva March 2005: 5-6, 10.)59 Drawn from Kaelin 2006.60 See Handbook on Housing and Property Restitution <strong>for</strong> Refugees andDisplaced Persons 2007.61 Acemoglu et al. 2004; Acemoglu and Johnson 2005; de Soto 1989,2000; Roll and Talbott 2001.62 The proportion of owners resisting expropriation against marketvalue compensation is high. In a case reported by Galiani and Schargrodsky(2004: 5) <strong>the</strong> proportion is 5 resisting to 8 agreeing.63 See Chapter 1, Section 2; de Soto 1989: 201-230.64 See de Soto 2000: 200-202.65 See USAID 2007: 21-23.66 Gradstein 2006.67 Chong and Gradstein 2007b show that inequality subverts egalitarianproperty rights systems.68 ‘…<strong>the</strong> initial conditions had lingering effects, not only becausecertain fundamental characteristics of New World economies were difficult to change, but also because government policies and institutionstended to reproduce <strong>the</strong>m. Specifi cally, in those societies that beganwith extreme inequality, elites were better able to establish a legalframew<strong>ork</strong> that insured <strong>the</strong>m disproportionate shares of political power,and to use that greater infl uence to establish rules, laws, and o<strong>the</strong>rgovernment policies that advantaged members of <strong>the</strong> elites relative tonon-members — contributing to persistence over time of <strong>the</strong> high degreeof inequality.’ (Sokoloff and Engerman 2000).69 Coudouel et al. 2007: 6.70 Chong and Gradstein 2007a; Dabla-Norris et al. 2007.71 Acemoglu and Robinson 2005.72 Gradstein 2006; Deininger and Squire 1998.73 Chong and Gradstein 2007.74 USAID 2007.75 Jacoby and Minten 2005.76 Major comparative reviews of evidence of impacts on investmentand access to credit suggest that titling and registration of land is mostlikely to be effective where robust <strong>for</strong>mal fi nancial markets already existand where <strong>the</strong>re are incentives <strong>for</strong> investment created by factorssuch as proximity to urban markets and good quality land (Bruce andMigot-Adholla 1994; Feder and Nishio (1996). Studies that particularlyfocus on <strong>the</strong> poor suggest that credit and o<strong>the</strong>r benefi ts may be heavilyskewed toward large landholders (Carter and Olinto 2003).77 Almost never occurs outside developed countries: Okoth Ogendo1999; Alden Wily and Mbaya 2001; Hunt 2004.78 For example, in India, <strong>the</strong> amount of bribes paid every year by usersof land administration services is estimated at US$700 million (TransparencyInternational India 2005), three-quarters of <strong>the</strong> public spendingon science, technology, and environment.79 China was <strong>the</strong> fi rst centrally planned economy to link <strong>the</strong> collectivesystem to household size farms. Households were allowed to contract<strong>the</strong>ir share of <strong>the</strong> collective land and cultivate it individually, inreturn paying to <strong>the</strong> collective a fi xed amount of produce, taxes andfees (Household Responsibility System). In a fi rst stage, results wereimpressive as China’s grain production increased from 321.2 milliontons in 1979 to 407.1 million tons in 1984 (a fi ve-year increase of 27percent, or 5.4 percent a year). The increase slowed down afterwards to469.5 million tons in 2004. Fur<strong>the</strong>r gains seem more diffi cult to achieve.More investment and access to credit is required in order to improve irrigation,drainage, land terracing, soil upgrades, etc. Today, <strong>the</strong> Chinesefarmers’ use rights suffer from land grabbing by offi cials or by frequentand unpredictable readjustments of land rights. The number of sticksin farmer’s property rights bundle is still insuffi cient; <strong>the</strong> practice ofland readjustment has been <strong>the</strong> main source of land tenure insecurityin China since <strong>the</strong> decollectivisation of agriculture. Farmers are <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>eunwilling to make productivity-enhancing investments that wouldrequire several years to recover, such as irrigation, drainage, or landterracing. See Prosterman 2006: 113. In 1998 <strong>the</strong> Government of Tajikistan,with <strong>the</strong> support of <strong>the</strong> World Bank, began <strong>the</strong> implementationof <strong>the</strong> Farm Privatization Support Project (FPSP). Ten farms covering anarea of 17,000 hectares were privatised to individual families. First,farms were divided into <strong>the</strong>ir constituent brigades and per capita landwas divided among farmers. Inheritable but not tradable land use certificates were provided by <strong>the</strong> state land committee to individual farm-116


ers, refl ecting <strong>the</strong> allocation of lands. Second, water user associationswere <strong>for</strong>med and a community-managed water provision system, a watercharge collection mechanism, and maintenance of <strong>the</strong> intra-farmwater distribution system were established. Third, a grant of US$300per hectare was provided to farmers to obtain crop inputs or any farmneeds to start farming as an independent family farmer. Fourth, technicalassistance was provided to farmers by using demonstration plots.In Tajikistan <strong>the</strong> government owns <strong>the</strong> land, but its use right is vestedwith <strong>the</strong> Tajik citizen, family, individual, or group of individuals. Theland use right is inheritable but this right cannot be rented, leased,transferred to non-family members, mortgaged, or sold. The land useright is registered and is backed by <strong>the</strong> government. In <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong>FPSP, land tenure rights are now vested with <strong>the</strong> farmer; in case of <strong>for</strong>merprivatisation programmes, land use rights are collective, with <strong>the</strong>farm manager making decisions on behalf of <strong>the</strong> members. This differenceresults in different incentive structures and differential impacts ofindividual land tenure and collective land tenure on <strong>the</strong> incentives <strong>for</strong>and incomes of farmers. Sattar and Mohib 2007: 463-465.80 Alden Wily 2006.81 See Mendoza 2006.82 Izumi 2007: 14.83 Bruce et al. 2006: 47-51.84 Alden Wily and Mbaya 2001; Alden Wily 2003; Alden Wily 2006 passim.85 Hardin 1968.86 Bruce and Migot-Adholla 1994; Mighot-Adholla et al. 1994a; Collierand Gunning 1999.87 Alden Wily 2006.88 Alden Wily 2002.89 Bruce and Migto-Adholla 1994; Deininger 2003; Augustinus 2003.90 Alden Wily 2002, 2006b, 2006c.91 Deininger et al. 2007.92 See Bruce et al. 2006: 107-142.93 CLEP Kenya; CLEP Pakistan; CLEP Philippines; CLEP Uganda.94 Field 2004.95 Deininger and Chamorro 2004; Bruce and Migot-Adholla 1994; Jacobyand Minten 2005.96 Bruce and Migot-Adholla 1994; Feder and Nishio 1996.97 Feder, Onchan and Raparia 1988; Galiani and Schargrodsky 200498 In Cambodia, people pay US$200 to $300 and more in in<strong>for</strong>malfees <strong>for</strong> title to land in urban areas. See World Bank 2002: 7.99 Augustinus 2003: 25.100 Palmer 1998: 87.101 Burns 2006: 3.102 In Mexico, ‘some ejidos prefer not to regularize <strong>the</strong> land <strong>for</strong> humansettlements to evade paying <strong>the</strong> land tax, which obviously promotes in<strong>for</strong>malityin land markets’ (UN-Habitat 2005a: 107). A similar outcomeis reported from Pakistan, rein<strong>for</strong>cing <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> taxes to be set ataf<strong>for</strong>dable levels and <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> revenue to fi nance services people wantand are willing to pay <strong>for</strong> (Payne 1997: 8).103 In Indonesia, property tax re<strong>for</strong>m increased revenues under reducedadministrative and compliance costs. Careful introduction of <strong>the</strong>changes minimized resistance. Political will was a paramount requirement.Although <strong>the</strong>re were pre-existing property taxes, dramatic adjustmentswere required to deliver <strong>the</strong> changes. These were carefully pilotedto test and improve procedures, to train staff and identify taxpayerresponses to <strong>the</strong> changes. Indonesia’s tertiary educational institutionsnow train about 600 property tax administrators a year. Colombia’s useof <strong>the</strong> self-assessment method has resulted in an increased tax baseand revenues and has allowed <strong>the</strong> cadastre to be updated. In Kenya, <strong>the</strong>primary obstacles to property tax re<strong>for</strong>m have been lack of political willand weak administration. Taxpayers need to perceive <strong>the</strong> linkage withimproved local services and also need to be confi dent of fair administration.For an overview see Bird and Slack 2002104 Condominium is ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>m of housing tenure. It is <strong>the</strong> legalterm used in <strong>the</strong> United States and in most provinces of Canada <strong>for</strong> atype of joint ownership of real property in which portions of <strong>the</strong> propertyare commonly owned and o<strong>the</strong>r portions are individually owned. In Australiaand <strong>the</strong> Canadian province of British Columbia, <strong>the</strong> legal term <strong>for</strong>this is ‘strata title’. In Quebec, it is known as syndicates of co-ownership.In <strong>the</strong> United Kingdom, <strong>the</strong> equivalent is commonhold, but this<strong>for</strong>m of ownership was only introduced in 2004.105 See Deininger et al. 2007.106 See e.g. Payne 2002; Durand-Lasserve 2003.107 See Galiani and Schargrodsky 2004. The authors study a naturalexperiment whereby land titling was ex post granted to a large group ofindividual squatters. The analysis reveals marked changes in economicresponses of this group relatively to <strong>the</strong> controlled group of squatters.The study shows only modest positive effect of land titling on accessto mortgage credit, and no impact on access to o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>ms of credit.It shows no effect on <strong>the</strong> labour income of <strong>the</strong> households holding newtitles. However, it is shown that moving a poor household from uncertainusufructuary rights to a more complete bundle of property rightssubstantially increased investment in <strong>the</strong> family houses. Land titlingreduced <strong>the</strong> size of families. These smaller families invested more in<strong>the</strong> education of <strong>the</strong>ir children. In sum, entitling <strong>the</strong> poor increases <strong>the</strong>irinvestment both in <strong>the</strong> house and in <strong>the</strong> human capital of <strong>the</strong>ir children.This is a very concrete example of legal empowerment with positive longterm effects. Property rights contribute to human development under anintergenerational and behavioural perspective.108 On Africa see a series of reports by IIED at: http://www.iied.org/NR/drylands/projects/landregistration.html109 Ejido land in Mexico, which can be trans<strong>for</strong>med into fully alienablefreehold land based on a qualifi ed vote by <strong>the</strong> assembly, is a goodexample. The fact that only about a tenth of ejidos chose to go this routeillustrates that, even at high levels of per capita income, many userssee benefi ts from maintaining communal relations to be greater thanthose from full individualisation of rights.110 Cotula 2007111 ‘Land Tenure Re<strong>for</strong>m and Gender Equality,’ UNRISD Researchand Policy Brief 4 (January, 2006) 1. In most Indian states <strong>the</strong> patta,or leasehold right over government land occupied by <strong>the</strong> poor is givenjointly in <strong>the</strong> name of <strong>the</strong> husband and wife. In Andhra Pradesh, <strong>the</strong>patta is in <strong>the</strong> name of women only. There have not been any studies on117


<strong>the</strong> outcomes or impacts of this practice. Banerjee 1999..112 UN-HABITAT 2006; Strickland 2004.113 Deere and Leon 2003.114 UN-HABITAT 2006.115 Agarwal 1994: 272.116 Drawn from Baechtold 2006.117 Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD) of June 5, 1992, http://www.biodiv.org/convention/articles.asp118 http://www.wipo.int/freepublications/en/tk/920/wipo_pub_920.pdf119 http://www.wipo.int/tk/en/laws/pdf/suigeneris_folklore.pdf120 http://www.wipo.int/edocs/mdocs/tk/en/wipo_grtkf_ic_9/wipo_grtkf_ic_9_inf_4.pdf121 For related aspects of bureaucratic justice <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor see Chapter1, Section 3.122 Ibid.123 CLEP Indonesia; CLEP Sri Lanka: 27; CLEP Philippines.124 In Peru, re<strong>for</strong>ms, particularly those that required congressionalapproval of laws, were promoted with <strong>the</strong> active participation of beneficiaries.The proposal to modify <strong>the</strong> Civil Code to permit <strong>the</strong> administrative,ra<strong>the</strong>r than judicial, declaration of adverse possession wasmet with a political debate based on different academic positions. To<strong>the</strong> extent to which <strong>the</strong> defi nition depended on a legislative option andrequired political support, COFOPRI disseminated <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m proposalamong <strong>the</strong> leaders of <strong>the</strong> settlements who would benefit from it and facilitated<strong>the</strong> organisation of <strong>the</strong> leadership to defend <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m proposalsbe<strong>for</strong>e Congress. A group of leaders lobbied members of Congress ofdiverse political sectors in order to demonstrate that <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms wouldbenefi t more than 100,000 families only in Lima, which was incentiveenough to obtain congressional approval.125 Through <strong>the</strong> intervention of COFOPRI it was determined that <strong>the</strong>leaders would w<strong>ork</strong> with <strong>the</strong> technical staff of <strong>the</strong> institution to obtain<strong>the</strong> technical and legal in<strong>for</strong>mation needed to carry out <strong>the</strong> requiredactions. In this stage legal obstacles to <strong>the</strong> regularisation of propertyin favour of its occupants would be identifi ed, such as cases of privateproperty, archaeological land, or in a risk zone. The participationof leaders enabled <strong>the</strong> settlers to appreciate <strong>the</strong> diffi culties that COFO-PRI confronted in regularising properties, made <strong>the</strong>ir expectations morerealistic regarding <strong>the</strong> time required to conclude <strong>the</strong> delivery of titlingservices, and made <strong>the</strong>m aware about <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms and complementaryactions.126 In Peru, COFOPRI developed <strong>the</strong> capacity to continuously improvere<strong>for</strong>ms through a series of incremental changes based on a learningby-doingapproach. The drafting of new laws was linked to <strong>for</strong>malisationprocesses (0, 1 and 2) which ensured that experiences and lessonslearned at <strong>the</strong> fi eld level were incorporated into <strong>the</strong> normative framew<strong>ork</strong>.For example, as <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>malisation process advanced, COFOPRI,through inputs from fi eld staff and community representatives, uncoverednew <strong>for</strong>ms of in<strong>for</strong>mality that were not identifi ed in <strong>the</strong> pilot project,like ‘pueblos tradicionales’ (ancient in<strong>for</strong>mal settlements in Arequipa).COFOPRI and RPU w<strong>ork</strong>ed toge<strong>the</strong>r to develop legally sound and effi cientsolutions to <strong>the</strong>se problems. New procedures were developed and testedat <strong>the</strong> organisational level and once validated, incorporated into <strong>the</strong>legal framew<strong>ork</strong>.127 See FAO 2007. For general issues of public administration re<strong>for</strong>msee Chapter 1, Section 3.128 Also recommended in CLEP Philippines, Ethiopia, Kenya, Uganda,Indonesia, Tanzania, Sri Lanka.129 See Chapter 1, passim.130 Center of Advanced Study 2007: 122.131 World Bank, World Development Report 2002: 14.132 Computerising records in <strong>the</strong> Indian state of Karnataka undera PPP model is estimated to have saved users US$16 million in bribes(Lobo and Balakrishnan 2002). Automating registration and <strong>the</strong> associatedland valuation allowed outsourcing to <strong>the</strong> private sector whichsignifi cantly improved access and resulted in cuts in stamp duty from14 percent to 8 percent while quadrupling tax revenue from US$120 toUS$480 million.133 See Prahalad 2005: 87-88.134 See FAO 2007: 25. See e.g. CLEP Uganda, Grassroots Academy,Property Section; CLEP Ethiopia (p.11 ss.) analyses how <strong>the</strong> current landsystem with state ownership gives <strong>the</strong> state (i.e. <strong>the</strong> individuals controlling<strong>the</strong> state) immense power over peasants.135 Fernandes 2006.136 FAO 2007: 50.137 The Singapore urban planning experience demonstrates that given<strong>the</strong> will and effi ciency of implementation, it is possible to plan aheadand promote organised growth. The unauthorized settlements of Delhi,India, that are regularised in <strong>the</strong> late 1970s offer ano<strong>the</strong>r example.These settlements have seen signifi cant improvement following regularisationdue to implementation of layout plans and extension of civicservices by government agencies. Residents <strong>the</strong>re have come to acquirefull tenurial security, resulting in <strong>the</strong>ir making fur<strong>the</strong>r investments atindividual and community levels and improving <strong>the</strong> quality of <strong>the</strong> microenvironment.In Malaysia, <strong>the</strong> government sets a ceiling price <strong>for</strong> lowcost housing, at RM25,000 per unit <strong>for</strong> people with household income ofless than RM750 per month and requires <strong>the</strong> private sector to constructlow cost housing (30 percent quota provision) in every residential development.These urban planning ef<strong>for</strong>ts need to be made more widelyreplicated at <strong>the</strong> community and city level. Yuen 2002, 2004, 2005.138 Jacobs 1961; Newman 1972.139 Barzel 1997; Alexander 2001.140 Steuteville 2005; Congress <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> New Urbanism 1999.141 CLEP Report from South America (Brazil).142 Santiago 2004.143 Banerjee 2005.144 Government of India 1998.145 Government of India 1998.146 An external evaluation of <strong>the</strong> scheme showed that <strong>the</strong> 2,800families have improved <strong>the</strong>ir housing situation considerably and haveorganised <strong>the</strong>mselves to procure infrastructure incrementally. 600families have been gainfully employed in <strong>the</strong> home-based carpet weav-118


ing industry through <strong>the</strong> scheme. (Siddiqui and Khan 1994; UN-HABITAT1991).147 Govt. of India 2004.148 See Chapter 4, which covers this topic.149 For instance, in <strong>the</strong> city of Uttaradit, <strong>the</strong> initiative started withsurvey mapping of all <strong>the</strong> slums and small pockets of squatters, identifyinglandowners and those slums that could stay and that neededto be relocated. This helped link community organisations and beganbuilding a community netw<strong>ork</strong> supported by young architects, a groupof monks and <strong>the</strong> mayor. Toge<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong>y sought to fi nd housing solutions<strong>for</strong> 1000 families within <strong>the</strong> existing city fabric through differenttechniques such as land sharing, re-blocking, in-situ upgrading andrelocation. Their city-wide housing plan became <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> cityupgrading programme under Baan Mankong and now includes infrastructureimprovements, urban regeneration, canal cleaning, wastelandreclamation and park development. Boonyabancha 2005.150 For a broader discussion of this issue see Chapter 1, section 4.151 Brustinow 2006.152 Handbook on Housing and Property Restitution <strong>for</strong> Refugees andDisplaced Persons 2007.153 Kranton and Swamy 1999; World Bank 2003.154 Although <strong>the</strong>ir initial level of income and assets was not significantly different from <strong>the</strong> average, <strong>the</strong>ir level of assets and incomein 1999 was more than 50 percent above <strong>the</strong> mean while <strong>the</strong>ir level ofconsumption was about 20 percent above <strong>the</strong> average.155 Deininger et al. 2007b.156 Rolfes 2006: 127-128.157 Bledsoe 2006.158 See Prahalad 2005; Kasturi Rangan et al. 2007.159 Apasco, a Mexican subsidiary of Holcim, realised that sellingcement through a chain of middlemen dramatically raises prices. Byopening new distribution centres in remote areas where cement couldbe purchased bag-by-bag and providing technical and safety advice tobuilders, Apasco was able to sell responsibly to <strong>the</strong> poor. The benefi ts to<strong>the</strong> local communities included a facilitated access to building materialsat af<strong>for</strong>dable prices. Apasco staff also offered consulting serviceson do-it-yourself building techniques. Lessons learned in Mexico arebeing studied at headquarters to see if this model can be replicatedelsewhere. (Source: WBCSD 2005: 47)160 WBCSD 2005.161 Delta Café buys raw materials from poor communities in EastTimor, creating sustainable livelihoods and gaining market rewards <strong>for</strong>producing a socially responsible product. Delta Café is part of <strong>the</strong> NabeiroGroup of food companies, and is <strong>the</strong> market leader <strong>for</strong> coffee inPortugal, with a market share of 38 percent. The company developed<strong>the</strong> Delta Timor brand and marketed it as socially responsible coffeeafter getting involved with <strong>the</strong> growing communities in <strong>the</strong> remotehills of East Timor, a <strong>for</strong>mer Portuguese colony. This project is alreadyturning a profi t, thanks to <strong>the</strong> popularity of <strong>the</strong> new Delta Timor brandamong Portuguese consumers, promoted strongly by its partner Sonae,<strong>the</strong> country’s biggest retailer. Delta welcomes competition in <strong>the</strong> regionfrom o<strong>the</strong>r coffee-producing companies, as this will improve <strong>the</strong> coffeeproducing techniques of all farmers. (Source: WBCSD 2005: 50.)162 Through its Solar Rural Operations, Shell Solar is bringing solarelectricity and equipment directly to remote households in six developingcountries (India, Sri Lanka, Philippines, South Africa, China, andMorocco). In Sri Lanka a typical solar electricity system powers sevenlights and sells <strong>for</strong> around $550-600. With 10,000 units sold by ShellSolar, benefi ts have included: 300 new jobs, mostly in rural areas;signifi cant reduction in undesirable emissions by replacing kerosenelamps and diesel generators; bright light, making reading, cooking, andeducation easier; and convenient power to connect with <strong>the</strong> world viatelevision and radio. This distribution model w<strong>ork</strong>s, reaching break-evenin 2001. Two barriers were overcome: availability of systems and <strong>the</strong>ability of householders to pay. (Source: WBCSD 2005: 58.)163 BP: Focusing on <strong>the</strong> macroeconomic impact of its operations, BPis w<strong>ork</strong>ing with <strong>the</strong> government in Trinidad and Tobago to encouragewider business ownership. The aim is both to promote good governanceand to create a pool of businesses that can not only supply BP’s operations<strong>the</strong>re but also compete on a world scale, beyond <strong>the</strong> present gasboom. Trinidad and Tobago is <strong>the</strong> largest liquefi ed natural gas (LNG)exporter to <strong>the</strong> United States, and BP aims to double its share of globalLNG business by 2010. Helping locally-owned contractors develop globalscale capabilities and become signifi cant part of BP’s current supplychain contributes to <strong>the</strong> government’s aim of achieving a dynamic andsustainable economy through <strong>the</strong> building of knowledge-based skills.This will in turn allow <strong>the</strong> overall economy to continually evolve and recreateitself beyond oil and gas. Success will also allow <strong>the</strong> governmentand people to see <strong>the</strong>mselves, perhaps <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> fi rst time, not merely asexporters of gas, but exporters of intellectual capital. This could becomereality as a result of local learning institutions, w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce and companiesbecoming global experts in <strong>the</strong> industry. Source: WBCSD 2005: 53.164 CLEP In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses India: 10.165 See also CLEP Uganda: 22; Guyers 2005; Chanell 2006.166 USAID 2006. In Nigeria, <strong>for</strong> instance, only 10 percent of whatcan be used as collateral in <strong>the</strong> US can legally be used as collateral.This means that Nigerians have a thinner and less valuable bundle ofproperty rights in moveable and intangible property. A poor woman inCambodia may well have a crop in <strong>the</strong> fi eld or a pig or cow in a pasture.If she is able to use <strong>the</strong>se to obtain a lawful loan she has one additionalcredit option. If she can use <strong>the</strong> moveable property she owns as collateralshe is likely to be offered a lower interest rate and better terms from<strong>the</strong> lender than if <strong>the</strong> loan was unsecured. If lenders are legally able toaccept such property as collateral she is also less likely to have to resortto an in<strong>for</strong>mal moneylender when she needs credit.167 Savafi an, Fleisig and Steinbuks 2006. For example, in Bolivia,Bancosol offers borrowers who use collateral larger loans, longer loanterms, and lower interest rates than <strong>the</strong>y do borrowers without collateral.In Romania, after a new collateral law was enacted in 2000<strong>the</strong> interest rate dropped by 6 percent and <strong>the</strong> interest rate on lendingdropped by 20 percent.168 IADB 2005, Unlocking Credit.169 USAID 2006: 4.170 USAID 2006: 5.171 Source: Grameen Bank.172 Critics are sceptical about <strong>the</strong> repayment fi gure and charge that119


<strong>the</strong> system leads to <strong>the</strong> borrower becoming dependent on <strong>the</strong> loans. Thebank has also been criticised <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> level of interest rates that climb ashigh as 20 percent <strong>for</strong> loans to businesses that generate income. (InternationalHerald Tribune, Asia-Pacifi c, Oct 13, 2006). Current amountof outstanding loans stands at TK 33.42 billion (US$484.29 million).During <strong>the</strong> past 12 months (April 06 to March 07) Grameen Bank disbursedTk. 50.42billion (US$727.85 million). Projected disbursement <strong>for</strong>2007 is Tk 65.00 billion (US$930 million), i.e. monthly disbursement ofTk 5.42 billion (US$77.50 million). End of <strong>the</strong> year outstanding loan isprojected to be at Tk. 40.00 billion (US$572 million).173 These companies have <strong>the</strong> following loan liability to GrameenBank :Grameen Fund : Tk 373.2 million (US$6.38 million); GrameenKrishi Foundation : Tk 19 million (US$.33 million); Grameen Motsho(Fisheries) Foundation : Tk 15 million (US$.26 million); Grameen Bankprovided guarantees in favour of <strong>the</strong> following organisations while <strong>the</strong>ywere receiving loans from <strong>the</strong> government and <strong>the</strong> fi nancial organisations.These guarantees are still in effect. Grameen Shakti : Tk 9 million(US$0.12 million); Grameen Motsho (Fisheries) Foundation : Tk 8 million(US$0.11 million); Grameen Kalyan; Grameen Kalyan (well-being) is aspin off company created by Grameen Bank.174 Source: Grameen Bank.175 Drawn from Garcia-Bolivar 2007.176 Studies in <strong>the</strong> Dominican Republic, Nicaragua, and Vietnam showthat insecure land ownership reduced <strong>the</strong> propensity to rent and limitedtransactions to pre-existing social netw<strong>ork</strong>s, despite <strong>the</strong> associatedineffi ciency. See Macours/de Janvry and Sadoulet 2005; Deininger andChamorro 2004; Deininger and Jin 2003. Fear of losing <strong>the</strong> land, toge<strong>the</strong>rwith explicit rental restrictions, was <strong>the</strong> main reason <strong>for</strong> suboptimalper<strong>for</strong>mance of rental markets in Ethiopia (Deininger, Ayalew and Alemu2006).177 The case of China illustrates that, in <strong>the</strong> context of broad-basedland access, guaranteed long term rent can provide greatly enhanceefficiency while at <strong>the</strong> same time providing a basic social safety net ata cost that is much below alternative government programems, <strong>the</strong>rebyallowing government to spend scarce resources on provision of productiveinfrastructure instead of safety nets. Also, having <strong>the</strong>ir basic subsistenceensured allows Chinese households to take on greater risks innon-agricultural businesses and, with policies to foster lease markets<strong>for</strong> land, contributes signifi cantly to <strong>the</strong> emergence of a vibrant nonfarmeconomy.178 See also CLEP Sri Lanka: 27-28; CLEP Tanzania.179 Banerjee and Iyer 2005; Nugent and Robinson 2002.180 Bruce 2006: 47-51.181 Bird and Slack 2006.182 CLEP Kenya, CLEP Uganda, CLEP Indonesia, CLEP Philippines;Deininger et al. 2006.183 For a more detailed analysis and recommendations see Chapter1, Section 2 of this report. Evidence from Uganda suggests that greaterknowledge of laws providing tenure security to customary tenure leadsto higher land-related investment but that, with less than a third ofhouseholds — normally <strong>the</strong> better off — being well-in<strong>for</strong>med, ef<strong>for</strong>tsto disseminate in<strong>for</strong>mation could signifi cantly impact productivity andequity (Deininger et al. 2006.)184 Eighty-nine neighbourhoods were upgraded or created under <strong>the</strong>program in Ceara, Brazil, to <strong>the</strong> benefi t of 25,300 families (more than100,000 people) using an intergovernmental/community partnership ofself-help housing, whereby <strong>the</strong> state fi nanced infrastructure and housingmaterials, <strong>the</strong> municipality furnished <strong>the</strong> land and <strong>the</strong> benefi ciariesconstructed <strong>the</strong>ir own housing, with technical assistance. 100,000people got access to housing and property rights. Importantly, <strong>the</strong>seinvestments were achieved with a per-family investment of US$2,100,including project, w<strong>ork</strong>s, land and social mobilisation. The main lessonsfrom this programme are that Government programmes <strong>for</strong> housing canbecome a mechanism <strong>for</strong> property rights creation or regularization, raisingstrong incentives <strong>for</strong> communities’ contribution to <strong>the</strong> upgrade ofliving conditions through investments in services and houses construction.(Ceara, Brazil: Urban Development and Water Resources ManagementProject).185 In <strong>the</strong> 1960s, Singapore faced a serious problem of housingshortage. In response, <strong>the</strong> government set clear targets <strong>for</strong> housingprovision and reorganised <strong>the</strong> housing industry. It passed <strong>the</strong> Housingand Development ordinance in 1960 which created <strong>the</strong> Housing andDevelopment Board (HDB) with a strong mandate and resources to deliverhousing units. The fi rst priority of <strong>the</strong> agency was to build as manylow-cost housing units as quickly as possible. The housing that wasinitially built was largely <strong>for</strong> rental by low-income groups. Forty yearson, approximately 85 percent of Singapore’s 3.4m resident population iscurrently living in HDB housing. The majority of <strong>the</strong>se people own <strong>the</strong>irhomes. In 1964 <strong>the</strong> government introduced <strong>the</strong> Home Ownership <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>People scheme to help all citizens to buy homes up to <strong>the</strong>ir capabilityas consumers. The aim is to give citizens including <strong>the</strong> poor an assetin <strong>the</strong> country. The lowest income citizens are not excluded from <strong>the</strong>housing system. This has encouraged <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mulation of policies aimedat reducing <strong>the</strong> cost of housing and easing access to owner occupationin public housing <strong>for</strong> all including <strong>the</strong> lower income residents. Theconsequence of <strong>for</strong>mal housing titles is increased housing investment,a greater sense of stakeholding and interest in <strong>the</strong> maintenance, qualityand design of <strong>the</strong> public housing. After more than 4 decades of publichousing development, an increasing number of people have personallychosen high-rise living and 82.5 percent of households in public housinghave expressed contentment at <strong>the</strong> idea of always living in publichousing fl ats.186 World Bank 2003a.187 For <strong>the</strong> most part of <strong>the</strong> following passages see Martinez 2007.188 Satterthwaite 2005.189 McKeon 1962; Harris 2004; Krieger and Higgins 2002; Von Hoffman1998.190 Since 1984, Grameen Bank is giving housing loans, <strong>the</strong> maximumbeing fi xed at Tk 15,000 (US$217) at an interest rate of 8 percent. It isto be repaid over a period of 5 years in weekly installments. 644,965houses have been constructed with <strong>the</strong> housing loans averaging Tk13,194 (US$191). A total amount of Tk 8.51 billion (US$203.98 million)has been disbursed <strong>for</strong> housing loans. During <strong>the</strong> past 12 months (fromApril’06 to March’07) 13,590 houses have been built with housing loansamounting to Tk 143.86 million (US$2.07 million) (Grameen Bank).191 Buckley and Kalarichal 2006.192 For Eastern European countries see Palacin and Shelbourne,2005: 7. Struyk and Turner, 1986, <strong>the</strong> study of South Korea and <strong>the</strong>Philippines, noted that occupants with <strong>for</strong>mal sector titles, across allincome categories, enjoyed better quality housing in both countries.120


193 See Tomlinson 2007.194 UN-ESCAP 1994; Banerjee, 1995. Haryana Urban DevelopmentAuthority (HUDA) in India enters into partnership with private developersto develop townships in <strong>the</strong> highly sought-after periphery of Delhi. Thisland is under agricultural land ceiling and not available <strong>for</strong> urban use,except with <strong>the</strong> permission of HUDA with <strong>the</strong> condition that 20 percentof <strong>the</strong> housing should go to <strong>the</strong> poor.195 TDR is included as part of <strong>the</strong> national urban policy in Brazil.Implementation started with 10,000 houses <strong>for</strong> 120 co-operatives of<strong>the</strong> poor between 1989 and 1992 in Sao Paolo. (Fernandes, 2002.) NGOslike Instituto Polis continue to provide advocacy and technical and legalassistance to slum communities and land owners to implement <strong>the</strong>approach in several cities of Brazil. In Mumbai TDR is linked with <strong>the</strong>government’s policy of 1999 of providing houses free of cost to 4 millionslum dwellers in fi ve years. (Burra, 2005.)196 UN-ESCAP, 1994.197 See Panaritis, 2007.198 Guidance can be found in Alden Wily 2002. See also Deininger etal. 2007; see ILD 1994, 2002, 2004.199 Mosqueira, 2007.200 See Collier 2007: 135-140.201 Rajan, 2005.202 Collier 2007: 140-156.Chapter 2 BibliographyAcemoglu, D. and J.A. Robinson. 2005. Economic Origins of Democracyand Dictatorships. Cambridge University Press.Acemoglu, Daron, James Robinson and Simon Johnson. 2004. ‘Institutionsas <strong>the</strong> Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth.’NBER W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper No. 10481.ADB. 2002. Indigenous Peoples/Ethnic Minorities and Poverty Reduction:Philippines. Manila: Asian Development Bank.Agarwal, Bina. 1994. A Field of One’s Own. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press.Ahmed, Fauzia Erfan. 2007. ‘Microcredit, Segmentation, and PovertyAlleviation Strategy <strong>for</strong> Women.’ In: Kasturi Rangan et al.:15-24Alden Wily, Liz and Mbaya, S. 2001. Land, people and <strong>for</strong>ests in easternand sou<strong>the</strong>rn Africa at <strong>the</strong> beginning of <strong>the</strong> 21st Century.The impact of land relations of <strong>the</strong> role of communities in<strong>for</strong>est future. IUCN-EARO.Alden Wily, Liz. 2002. Getting <strong>the</strong> Process Right: Land Administrationas Governance: A discourse on <strong>the</strong> political economy ofland tenure management. Comments on <strong>the</strong> Legal Basis <strong>for</strong>Land Administration in an African Context. Paper presentedto <strong>the</strong> World Bank Land Policy Conference in Africa, April29-May 2 2002, Kampala, Uganda._______. 2003. Governance and Land Relations. A Review of Decentralizationof Land Administration and Management inAfrica. Land Tenure and Resources Series. InternationalInstitute <strong>for</strong> Environment and Development [IIED] London._______. 2004a. Putting Rural Land Registration in Perspective:The Afghanistan Case in Proceedings Land Administrationin Post Confl ict Areas; 71-93. International Federation ofSurveyors Commission 7 Cadastre and Land Management,2004. http://www.fi g.net/commission7/geneva_2004/index.htm (<strong>for</strong> original draft only)_______. 2004b. Rural Land Relations in Confl ict: A Way Forward.Policy Brief. Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit,Kabul August 2004. http://www.areu.org.af_______. 2005. From Meeting Needs to Honouring Rights: The Evolutionof Community Forestry Chapter 19 in The EarthscanReader in Forestry and Development (ed. Jeffrey Sayer)2005; 388-394. Earthscan UK (originally a Keynote Addressto <strong>the</strong> World Forestry Congress Quebec 2003)_______. 2006. The Commons and Customary <strong>Law</strong> in Modern Times:Rethinking <strong>the</strong> Orthodoxies. In From Knowledge to Action. EMwangi (ed.). CaPri, Washington._______. 2006b. Formalizing <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal: Is There a Way to SecureHuman Potential through Land Entitlement? A Review ofChanging Administration in Africa, in: Linking <strong>the</strong> Formaland In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy Concepts and Policies. Edited by B.Guha-khasnobis, R. Kunbur and E. Ostrom. Ox<strong>for</strong>d UniversityPress._______. 2006c. Land Rights Re<strong>for</strong>m and Governance in Africa: Howto Make it W<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong> 21st Century? UNDP October 2006.______. 2007. An Interim Note on Customary Land Tenure in Post-Confl ict Liberia.121


Alexander, E. 2001. ‘A Transaction Costs Theory of Land Use Planningand Development Control,’ Town Planning Review 72/1:45-76.Allanic, Benoît. 2003. «La nouvelle coutume urbaine: Évolutioncomparée des fi lières coutumières de la gestion foncièreurbaine dans les pays d’Afrique subSaharienne. Le cas deMandela Village, South Africa. » ISTED, DFID.Alston, Lee, Gary Libecap and Robert Schneider. 1996. ‘The Determinantsand Impact of Property Rights: Land Titles on <strong>the</strong>Brazilian Frontier.’ Journal of <strong>Law</strong>, Economics, and Organisation12:1 (1996): 1569-1614.Aristazabal, Nora and Andres Gomes.2004. ‘Improving Security withoutTitles in Bogotá.’ Habitat International 28/2.Asian Development Bank. 2004. Technical Assistance to <strong>the</strong> IslamicRepublic of Afghanistan <strong>for</strong> Capacity Building in LandPolicy and Administration Re<strong>for</strong>m. Manila: ADB.Augustinus, Clarissa and Barry, Michael. 2006. ‘Land ManagementStrategy Formulation in Post Confl ict Societies.’ SurveyReview 38: 668-681.Augustinus, Clarissa. 2003. ‘Handbook on Best Practices: Securityof Tenure and Access to Land — Implementation of <strong>the</strong>Habitat Agenda.’ UN-Habitat, Nairobi.Baechtold, Philippe. 2006. ‘Public Policy Objectives and IntellectualProperty Rights.’ In: de Soto/Cheneval 2006: 266-277.Banerjee, Abhijit and Lakshmi. Iyer. 2005. ‘History, Institutions andEconomic Per<strong>for</strong>mance: The Legacy of Colonial Land TenureSystems in India.’ Available at: http://econ-www.mit.edu/fi les/511Banerjee, Banashree. 2002. ‘Security of Tenure in Indian Cities.’ In:Durand-Lasserve, A. and Royston L. (eds.). Holding <strong>the</strong>irGround: Secure Land Tenure <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Urban in DevelopingCountries, London: Earthscan Publications, 37-58._______. 2004. ‘Maximising <strong>the</strong> impact of tenure and infrastructureprogrammes on housing conditions: <strong>the</strong> case of slums inIndian Cities’ paper presented at International Conferenceon Adequate and Af<strong>for</strong>dable Housing <strong>for</strong> All - Research,Policy, Practice, June 24-27, Toronto_______. 2005. ‘Recognition, Regularization and Relocation of Slumsin Madhya Pradesh.’ Background Note <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> design ofDFID supported Madhya Pradesh Urban Services <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>Poor (Mimeo)_______. 2006. ‘Land Titling in Urban and Peri-urban Areas in India:Experiences and Issues.’ Paper presented at <strong>the</strong> ResearchW<strong>ork</strong>shop on Social and Economic Impacts of Land titlingin Urban and Peri-urban Areas, Charney Manor, CharneyBassett, UK, 12-15 December 2006._______. 1995. ‘Urban Land: Is <strong>the</strong>re hope <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor?’ In: Singh,K. and Steinberg, F. (eds.), Urban India in Crisis, Ox<strong>for</strong>d,New Delhi.Barry, Michael. 2002. Periurban Agriculture and Tenure in South Africa:Strategies <strong>for</strong> Tenure Regularization. United Nations Foodand Agricultural Organisation (FAO) publication series,Rome.Barzel, Y. 1997. Economic Analysis of Property Rights, Cambridge, MA:Cambridge University Press.Benjaminsen, T. A. 2006. ‘The emerging <strong>for</strong>malisation agenda andsome empirical evidence from Africa.’A paper presented at<strong>the</strong> Colloque international: At <strong>the</strong> Frontier of Land Issues.Social Embeddedness of rights and public policy. MontpellierCampus ENSAM-INRA, France, May 17, 18 and19 2006.Bertaud A. and Malpezzi S. 2001. ‘Measuring <strong>the</strong> Costs and Benefi ts ofUrban Land Use Regulation: A Simple Model with an Applicationto Malaysia,’ Journal of Housing Economics 10/3:393-418.Besley, Timothy. 1995. ‘Property Rights and Investment Incentives:Theory and Evidence from Ghana,’ Journal of PoliticalEconomy 103(5), 903-937.Binswanger, Hans, Klaus Deininger and Gershon Feder. 1995. ‘Power,Distortions, Revolt, and Re<strong>for</strong>m in Agrarian Relations.’ InJ. Berman and T.N. Srinivasan (eds.). Handbook of DevelopmentEconomics. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, NorthHolland.Bird, M. and E. Slack. 2002. ‘Land and Property Taxation around <strong>the</strong>World: A Review 2002.’ Paper presented in Hungary andMexico at World Bank Policy SeminarsBlesoe, David. 2006. ‘Can Land Titling and Registration Reduce Poverty?’In Bruce et al. 2006: 143-174.Boonyabancha, Somsook. 2005. ‘Mainstreaming community led processes<strong>for</strong> housing and poverty alleviation: <strong>the</strong> developmentof CODI and <strong>the</strong> Baan Mankong Programme.’ Case Study21 — Thailand, available at http://www.community-planning.netBoudreaux, Karol. 2007. ‘State Power, Entrepreneurship, and Coffee:The Rwandan Experience.’ Mercatus Centre. EnterpriseAfrica! W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper_______. 2006. ‘The Effects of Property Titling in Langa Township,South Africa.’ Mercatus Policy Series, Policy Comment No.4, available at: http://www.enterprise-africa.org/repository/docLib/20060524_Langa.pdf_______. 2007. ‘Community-Based Natural Resource Managementand Poverty Alleviation in Namibia: A Case Study.’ MercatusPolicy Series, Policy Comment Nr. 10.Bruce, John W. and Migot-Adholla, S. (eds.). 1994. Searching <strong>for</strong> Securityof Land Tenure in Africa. Dubuque, IA: Kendall/Hunt.Bruce, John W. 2006. ‘Re<strong>for</strong>m of Land <strong>Law</strong> in <strong>the</strong> Context of World BankLending.’ in Bruce et al. 2006, pp. 11-65.Bruce, John W., Giovarelli, R. Giovarelli, L. Rolfes, D. Bledsoe and R.Mitchell. 2006. Land <strong>Law</strong> Re<strong>for</strong>m. Achieving DevelopmentPolicy Objectives. World Bank <strong>Law</strong>, Justice, and DevelopmentSeries. Washington: WB.Brustinow, Angelika. 2006. ‘Out of Court Dispute Resolution as aPractical Tool <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowerment”, in: NorwegianMinistry of Foreign Affairs, Legal Empowerment, issue 2,Oslo: 91-113.Buckley, Robert M. and Jerry Kalarickal. 2006. ‘Land Market Issues:The Mystery of Capital Revisited. Urban Land Policy — IsTitling <strong>the</strong> Answer?’ in Buckley and Kalarickal (eds.). Thirtyyears of World Bank Shelter Lending: Directions in DevelopmentInfrastructure. World Bank, Washington, DC.Burns, Tony. 2006. ‘International Experience with Land AdministrationProjects: a Framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> Monitoring of Pilots’. Paper122


presented at <strong>the</strong> National W<strong>ork</strong>shop on Land Policies andAdministration <strong>for</strong> Accelerated Growth and Poverty Reductionin <strong>the</strong> 21st Century (Jan 5-6) New Delhi.Burra, Sundar. 2005. Towards a Pro-Poor Framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> Slum-Upgradingin Mumbai, India,’ Environment and Urbanisation,17/1.Calder n Cockburn, Julio. 2004. ‘The <strong>for</strong>malisation of property in Peru2001-2002: The case of Lima,’ Habitat International 28:289-300Cantuarias, Fernando and Delgado, Miguel. 2004. ‘Peru’s urban landtitling program’ Case study from ‘Reducing poverty, sustaininggrowth — what w<strong>ork</strong>s, what doesn’t and why? Aglobal exchange <strong>for</strong> scaling up success.’ Shanghai, May25-27, World BankCarter, Michael and Pedro Olinto. 2003. ‘Getting Institutions ‘Right’<strong>for</strong> Whom? Credit Constraints and <strong>the</strong> Impact of PropertyRights on <strong>the</strong> Quantity and Composition of Investment,’American Journal of Agricultural Economics 85/1: 173-186.Cavallar, Georg. 2002. The Rights of Strangers. Theories of InternationalHospitality, <strong>the</strong> Global Community, and Political Justicesince Vitoria. Aldershot.Ceara, Brasil: Urban Development and Water Resources ManagementProject).Center <strong>for</strong> Advanced Study, in collaboration with <strong>the</strong> Ministry of LandManagement, Urban Planning and Construction — NationalCadastral Commission Secretariat, The World Bank— Justice <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor Program, and The German DevelopmentCooperation (GTZ). 2007. ‘Towards InstitutionalJustice? A Review of <strong>the</strong> W<strong>ork</strong> of Cambodia’s CadastralCommission in Relation to Land Dispute Resolution’ (<strong>for</strong>thcoming)Chanell, Wade. 2006. ‘Bringing More Dead Capital to Life’. RAFiNotes (Washington, DC: US AID).Cheneval, Francis. 2006. ‘Property Rights as Human Rights’, in: deSoto and Cheneval 2006: 11-17.Chiong-Javier, M. E. 1989. ‘Ownership and Property Rights Issues inWatershed Resource Management.’ Journal of PhilippineDevelopment 26/1: 101-113.Chong, A. and M. Gradstein. 2007a. ‘Inequality and In<strong>for</strong>mality’, availableat: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=910215Chong, A. and M. Gradstein. 2007b. ‘Inequality and Institutions.’Review of Economics and Statistics, <strong>for</strong>thcoming.COHRE. 2000. ‘Women and Housing Rights,’ Geneva, Switzerland:COHRE.Colchester, Marcus/Mackay, Fergus/Griffi ths, Tom and Nelson, Jon.2001. ‘A Survey of Indigenous Land Tenure’. Forest PeoplesProgramme, REF: RA 42/1, PE ç/173.Collier, Paul and J.W. Gunning. 1999. ‘The Microeconomics of AfricanGrowth, 1950-2000.’ Thematic Paper <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> AERC CollaborativeResearch Project on ‘Explaining African EconomicGrowth, 1950-2000.’Collier, Paul. 2007. The Bottom Billion. Why <strong>the</strong> Poorest Countries AreFailing and What Can be Done about it. Ox<strong>for</strong>d: Ox<strong>for</strong>dUniversity Press.Commission on Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor (CLEP), NationalConsultation Report, Property Rights, IndonesiaCLEP, National Consultation Report, In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses, India______. Property Rights, Kenya______. Property Rights, Pakistan______. Property Rights, Philippines: Mendoza, Amado M. 2006.‘Property Rights and <strong>the</strong> Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor in <strong>the</strong>Philippines’.______. South America Report______. In<strong>for</strong>mal Land Market, Sri Lanka______. Property Rights, Tanzania: Kironde, Lusugga. 2006. ‘<strong>Making</strong>Property Rights W<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor in Tanzania’.______. Property Rights, Uganda.______. Grassroots Academy, Property Section.Congress <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> NewUrbanism. 1999. Charter of <strong>the</strong> New Urbanism, New Y<strong>ork</strong>,McGraw Hill.Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD) of June 5, 1992, , at: http://www.wipo.int/freepublications/en/tk/920/wipo_pub_920.pdfCotula, Lorenzo (ed). 2007. Changes in ‘Customary’ Land Tenure Systemsin Africa. London/Rome: iied/FAO.Coudouel, Aline/Dani, Anis A./Paternostro, Stefano. 2007. SocialImpact Analysis of Re<strong>for</strong>ms. Lessons and Examples fromImplementation. Washington: IBRD/WB.Currey, James. 2004. International Federation of Surveyors, 2004, LandAdministration in Post Confl ict Areas. Proceedings of aSymposium held by FIG Commission 7, Geneva, April 2004.Dabla-Norris, E., Gradstein, M., and G. Inchauste. 2007. Journal ofDevelopment Economics, <strong>for</strong>thcoming.David, Cristina, et al. 2003. ‘Land re<strong>for</strong>m and land market transactionsin <strong>the</strong> Philippines.’ Terminal Report. Philippine Institute<strong>for</strong> Development Studies.De Soto, Hernando. 2006. ‘The Challenge of Connecting In<strong>for</strong>mal andFormal Property Systems’, in: De Soto/Cheneval 2006, pp.18-67._______. 2000. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in<strong>the</strong> West and Fails Everywhere Else. New Y<strong>ork</strong>: Basic Books._______. 1989. The O<strong>the</strong>r Path. New Y<strong>ork</strong>: Basic BooksDe Soto, Hernando and Cheneval, Francis (eds.). 2006. RealisingProperty Rights, Zurich: RüfferandRub.Deere, Carmen Diana and Magdalena Leon. 2003. ‘The Gender AssetGap: Land in Latin America,’ World Development 31(6:925-947.Deininger K. 2003. ‘Land Policies <strong>for</strong> Growth and Poverty Reduction’, AWorld Bank Policy Research Report, Washington DCDeininger, K. and Jin, S. 2003. ‘Land Sales and Rental Markets inTransition — Evidence from Rural Vietnam,’ WPS 3013,available at: http://econ.worldbank.orgDeininger, K., Alayew, D. and Yamano T. 2006. Legal Knowledge andEconomic Development: The Case of Land Rights in Uganda.Washington, DC: The World Bank.Deininger, K. and J. Chamorro. 2004. ‘Investment and Equity Effects ofLand Regularization: The Case of Nicaragua,’ AgriculturalEconomics 30/2: 101-116.123


Deininger, Klaus and Squire, Lyn. 1998. ‘New Ways of Looking at OldIssues: Inequality and Growth,’ Journal of DevelopmentEconomics 57: 259-287.Deininger, Klaus, Ayalew, Daniel and Alemu, Tekie. 2006. ‘Land Rentalin Ethiopia. Marshallian Ineffi ciency or Factor Market Imperfectionsand Tenure Insecurity as Binding Constraints?’available at: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/RPDL-PROGRAM/Resources/459596-1161903702549/S4_Ali.ppt#311,27,Folie 27Deininger, Klaus/ Ayalew, Daniel/ Holden, Stein/Zeevenbergen, Jaap.2007. ‘Rural Land Certifi cation in Ethiopia. Process, InitialImpact, and Implications <strong>for</strong> O<strong>the</strong>r African Countries,’World Bank Policy Research W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper WPS 4218.Deininger, Klaus/Jin, Songquing/Nagarajan, Hari K. 2007b. ‘Determinantsand Consequences of Land Sales Market Participation:Panel Evidence from India,’ World Bank PolicyResearch W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper WPS 4323.Deng, Yongheng, Della Zheng and Changfeng Ling. 2005. ‘An Early Assessmentof Residential Mortgage Per<strong>for</strong>mance in China,’The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 31/2.Di Gregorio, M., K. Hagedorn, M. Kirk, B. Korf, N. McCarty, and R. Meinzin-Dick.2005. ‘A Framew<strong>ork</strong> on Instutional Change <strong>for</strong>Resource Management and Poverty Reduction: The Role ofProperty Rights and Collective Action.’ Paper presented at<strong>the</strong> 99th seminar of <strong>the</strong> European Association of AgriculturalEconomists, Copenhagen, August 24-27, 2005.Diop, Maleye. 2007. ‘An example of an innovative participatory slumupgrading and land regularization initiative <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor inSenegal,’ Contribution to CLEP w<strong>ork</strong>ing group <strong>for</strong> Chapter2, on Property Rights.Du Plessis, Jean. 2005. ‘The Growing Problem of Forced Evictionsand <strong>the</strong> Crucial Importance of Community-Based, LocallyAppropriate Alternatives,’ Environment and Urbanization17/1: 123-134.Durand-Lasserve A. 2003. Land Issues and Security of Tenure. BackgroundReport prepared <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> UN Millenium Project TaskForce on Improving <strong>the</strong> Lives of Slum Dwellers. NationalCentre <strong>for</strong> Scientifi c Research, France.______. 2006. ‘Market-driven evictions and displacements: Implications<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> perpetuation of in<strong>for</strong>mal settlements in developingcities.’ In: Huchzermeyer, M., and Karam, A. (Editors).In<strong>for</strong>mal settlements. A perpetual challenge? University ofCape Town Press.Durand-Lasserve, A. and G. Payne. 2006. ‘Evaluating Impacts of UrbanLand Titling: Results and Implications: Preliminary Findings.’(Ms.)Economist . 2006. ‘Property and Poverty’, August 24.European Commission. 2007. Joint Report on Social Protection andSocial InclusionFood and Agricultural Organisation (FAO). 2002. Land administrationand rural development. Rome______. 2005. State of <strong>the</strong> World’s Forests, Rome______. 2006. ‘Reclaiming our lives: HIV and AIDS, women’s landand property rights, and livelihoods in sou<strong>the</strong>rn and EastAfrica,’ Cape Town, South Africa: HSRC Press.______. 2007. Good governance in land tenure and administration.Rome.Feder, G. and A. Nishio. 1996. ‘The Benefi ts of Land Registration andTitling: Economic and Social Perspectives,’ Land Use Policy15(1): 25-43.Feder, G./Onchan, T./Raparla, T. 1988. Collateral, guarantees and ruralcredit in developing countries: Evidence from Asia. AgriculturalEconomics 2: 231-245.Fernandes E. 2002. ‘Combining Tenure Policies, Urban Planning andCity Management in Brazil.’ In: Payne, Geoffrey (ed.). Land,Rights and Innovation - Improving Tenure Security <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>Urban Poor, London: ITDG.______. 2006. ‘Principles, Bases and Challenges of <strong>the</strong> NationalProgramme to Support Sustainable Urban Land Regularizationin Brazil.’ In: Huchzermeyer, M. and Karam, A. (eds.)In<strong>for</strong>mal settlements. A perpetual challenge? University ofCape Town Press, p. 62-83.Field, Erica. 2004. ‘Property rights, community public goods, andhousehold time allocation in urban squatter communities:Evidence from Peru.’ William and Mary <strong>Law</strong> Review 45(3):838—887.______.2005. ‘Property rights and investment in urban slums.’ Journalof European Economic Association, April-May 3 (2-3):279-290.Firmin-Sellers, K. and Sellers, P. 1999. ‘Expected failures and unexpectedsuccesses of land titling in Africa,’ World Development27/7: 1115-1999.Food and Agricultural Organisation (FAO). 1999. Women’s right to landand natural resources: some implications <strong>for</strong> a humanrightsbased approach. SD Dimensions, at: http://www.fao.org/sd/LTdirect/LTan0025.htm).Galiani, S. and E. Schargrodsky. 2004. ‘Property Rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>Poor: The Effect of Land Titling,’ At: http://200.32.4.58/~eschargr/______. 2004a. ‘Effects of land titling on child health,’ Economicsand Human Biology 2: 353-372.Garcia-Bolivar, Omar. 2007. ‘A Broader Defi nition of Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor’. Paper presented to <strong>the</strong> ANLEP w<strong>ork</strong>shop,Oslo Oct. 25-26, 2007 (mimeo).Giovarelli, Renée, Susana Lastarria-Cornhiel, Elizabeth Katz, and SueNichols. 2005. Gender Issues and Best Practices in LandAdministration Projects: A Syn<strong>the</strong>sis Report. Agricultureand Rural Development Department. The World Bank.Report No. 32571-GLB. Washington, DC: The World Bank.Glendon, Mary Ann. 2001. A World Made New. Eleanor Roosevelt and<strong>the</strong> Universal Declaration of Human Rights. New Y<strong>ork</strong>:Randam House.Golub, S. 2003. ‘Beyond <strong>the</strong> Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Orthodoxy: The Legal EmpowermentAlternative.’ Carnegie Endowment <strong>for</strong> InternationalPeace (CEIP) W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper No. 41.Government of India. 1998. National Housing and Habitat Policy, NewDelhi, Ministry of Urban Development._______. 2004. National Policy on Urban Street Vendors, New Delhi,Ministry of Urban Employment and Poverty Alleviation.Gradstein, Mark. 2006. ‘Inequality, Democracy, and <strong>the</strong> Protection of124


Property Rights.’ At: http://www.iew.unizh.ch/study/courses/downloads/markgradstein.pdfGROOTS Kenya. 2006. A Final Report on Grassroots Community InputTo <strong>the</strong> Commission on Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor— Hearing in Kenya, at: http://www.undp.org/legalempowerment/pdf/Microsoft%20Word%20-%20GROOTS%20Kenya%20Final%20Report%20_2_.pdfGuyers, Steven. 2005. ‘You’d be surprised what can be used <strong>for</strong>collateral,’ Denver Business Journal. Available at: http://www.bizjournals.com/denver/stories/2005/06/06/smallb6.htmlHaldrup, K. 2003. ‘From elitist standards to basic needs — diversifi edstrategies to land registration serving poverty alleviationobjectives’. Presented at 2nd FIG Regional Conference,Marrakech, Morocco December 2-5, 2003.Handbook on Housing and Property Restitution <strong>for</strong> Refugees andDisplaced Persons. Implementing <strong>the</strong> ‘Pinheiro Principles’(OCHA/IDD, UN HABITAT, UNHCR, FAO, OHCHR, NRC, IDMC2007).Hardin, Garret. 1968. ‘The Tragedy of <strong>the</strong> Commons,’ Science,162/3859: 1243-1248Hart, H.L.A. 1961. The Concept of <strong>Law</strong>. Ox<strong>for</strong>d: Clarendon Press.Heller, Michael A. 1998. ‘The Tragedy of <strong>the</strong> Anticommons: Property in<strong>the</strong> Transition from Marx to Markets’, Harvard <strong>Law</strong> Review111: 621-688.Hodgson, Stephen. 2004. ‘Land and Water — The Rights Interface.’FAO, LSP W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper 10. Access to Natural ResourcesSub-Programme.Hunt, Diana. 2004. ‘Unintended Consequences of Land Rights Re<strong>for</strong>m:The Case of <strong>the</strong> 1998 Uganda Land Act’ Development PolicyReview 22/2: 173-191.Hurwitz, A./Studdard, K./Williams, R. 2005. ‘Housing, Land, Propertyand Confl ict Management: Identifying Policy Options <strong>for</strong>Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Programming,’ Policy Paper. InternationalPeace Academy. FAO 2005. Access to rural land and landadministration after violent confl icts, FAO Land TenureStudies 8, Rome.Instituto Libertad y Democracia (ILD). 1994. ILD Estimates. Annex 1:Some of <strong>the</strong> ILD’s Practical Achievements and Annex 3:Business Formalization. Available at: http://www.ild.org.pe/pdf/annex/Annex_01.pdf and http://www.ild.org.pe/pdf/annex/Annex_03.pdf______. 2002. Supporting w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy: A PolicyFramew<strong>ork</strong>.______. 2004. ‘Dead Capital in Egypt.’ Available at: http://www.ild.org.pe/pdf/posters/egypt_en.pdf.______. 2005. Program to Formalize <strong>the</strong> Assets of <strong>the</strong> Poor in Tanzaniaand Streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> Rule of <strong>Law</strong>. Six Volumes. Dar esSalaam: ILD.Inter-American Development Bank (IADB). 2005. Unlocking Credit.Available at: http://idbdocs.iadb.org/wsdocs/getdocument.aspx?docnum=617000______. ‘Access to Financing <strong>for</strong> Small and Medium Enterprises’ In:Unlocking Credit, 2005 Report, available at: http://www.iadb.org/res/ipes/2005/docs/Chapter14Eng.pdfInter-Ministerial W<strong>ork</strong>ing Group. 2004. Afghanistan: Land Policy and itsImplementation. www.icarrd.org/en/icard_doc_down/national_Afghanistan.doc.International Center <strong>for</strong> Research on Women (ICRW). 2005. ‘PropertyOwnership <strong>for</strong> Women Enriches, Empowers and Protects:Toward Achieving <strong>the</strong> Third Millennium Development Goalto Promote Gender Equality and Empower Women,’ Washington,DCInternational Fund <strong>for</strong> Agricultural Development (IFAD). 2001. RuralPoverty Report, 2001. Available at: http://www.ifad.org/poverty/index.htmInternational Institute <strong>for</strong> Environment and Development (IIED). 2006.‘Local Innovation in Securing Land Rights in Africa: Lessonsfrom experience,’ Briefi ng Paper, IIED, LondonInter-Summit Property System Initiative. 2006. ‘The Inter-SummitProperty Systems Initiative (IPSI)’ Summary Presentation.Broad-based Economic Growth Team Regional SustainableDevelopment Bureau <strong>for</strong> Latin America and <strong>the</strong> CaribbeanUSAID Washington.Izumi, Kaori. 2007. ‘Gender-Based Violence and Property Grabbing inAfrica: A denial of Women’s Liberty and Security,’ Genderand Development 15(1): 11-23.Jacobs, J. 1961. The Death and Life of Great American Cities, NewY<strong>ork</strong>: Vintage.Jacoby, Hanan and Minten, Bart. 2005. ‘Is Land Titling In Sub-Saharan Africa Cost-Effective. Evidence from Madagascar’,available at: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTISPMA/Resources/Training-Events-and-Materials/Land_Titles_MG.pdfKaelin, Walter. 2006. ‘Internal Displacement and <strong>the</strong> Protection ofProperty,’ in: de Soto/Cheneval 2006: 175-185.Kasturi Rangan, V./Quelch, J.A./Herrero, G./Barton, B. 2007. BusinessSolutions <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Global Poor. San Francisco: Wiley andSons.Keefer, Philip and Knack, Stephen. 2002. ‘Polarization, Politics andProperty Rights: Links between inequality and Growth,’Public Choice 111: 127-154.Kranton, Rachel E. and Anand V. Swamy. 1999. ‘The Hazards of PiecemealRe<strong>for</strong>m: British Courts and <strong>the</strong> Credit Market in ColonialIndia,’ Journal of Development Economics 58: 1-24.Krieger, James and Higgins, Donna L. 2002. ‘Housing and Health: TimeAgain <strong>for</strong> Public Health Action,’ American Journal of PublicHealth 92/5: 758-768.Land Administration and Management Project (LAMP) 2, Departmentof Environment and Natural Resources. ‘Frequently askedquestions.’ Available at: www.phil-lamp.org/faq.htmlLand Tenure Lexicon. 2000. A glossary of terms from English andFrench speaking West Africa. Compiled by Rebeca Leonardand Judy Longbottom. London, available at: http://www.landcoalition.org/pdf/07_lexicon_FS_ied.pdfLobo, A. and Balakrishnan, S. 2002. Report on Service of BhoomiKiosks: An Assessment of Benefi ts by Users of <strong>the</strong> ComputerisedLand Records System in Karnataka. Bangalore:Public Affairs Centre.Locke, John. 1988 [1689]. Second Treatise of Government. New Y<strong>ork</strong>:125


Cambridge University Press. -- An argument <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> right toproperty, based on our property in ourselves.LTC/Land Tenure Center. 2002. ‘Assessment of USAID investmentsin land markets and property rights: Syn<strong>the</strong>sis based onUSAID documentation’ Land Tenure Center, University ofWisconsin, September______. 2002. ‘Guidelines <strong>for</strong> Analysis of USAID’s Land MarketProjects’ Documents Annex 3 Assessment Guidelines,University of Wisconsin______. 2002a. ‘An assessment of USAID’s investments in land marketsand property rights in Albania: documentary evidence’,Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin, SeptemberMacours, Karen/de Janvry, Alain/Sadoulet, Elisabeth.2004. ‘Insecurityof Property Rights and Matching in <strong>the</strong> Tenancy Market,’Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, UCB.CUDARE W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper 992. http://repositories.cdlib.org/are_ucb/992Martinez, Sylvia C. 2003. ‘Housing and Finance in Spain: A ComparativeStudy on Housing and Finance Principles.’ Unpublishedlecture delivered to Women in Housing and Finance, Jan.22, 2003. Washington, D.C.______. 2004. ‘Property Rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor a Global Perspective: ACase Study of Sites and Services in Mexicali, Baja Cali<strong>for</strong>nia.’Presentation be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong> United Nations EconomicCommission <strong>for</strong> Europe Land Development Forum in Rome,Italy. December 13-14.______. 2007. ‘In<strong>for</strong>mal Settlements in Developing Countries: ARights-Based Approach to Land Policies <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor’,Background Paper To The Presentation Be<strong>for</strong>e The UnitedNations Economic Commission <strong>for</strong> Europe W<strong>ork</strong>ing Party onLand Administration, And Committee on Housing and LandManagement, And The International Federation of Surveyors,28-31 March, A<strong>the</strong>ns, Greece.______. 2007a.’Toward a Pro-poor Global Housing Partnership’.Research Study <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Harvard Joint Center <strong>for</strong> HousingStudies In Support of <strong>the</strong> W<strong>ork</strong> of <strong>the</strong> Commission on LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor.McKeown, Thomas. R.G. Record. 1962. ‘Reasons <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Decline of Mortalityin England and Wales during <strong>the</strong> Nineteenth Century,’Population Studies 16/2: 94-122.Merriam, Dwight. 2005. The Complete Guide to Zoning. McGraw-Hill.Migot-Adholla, Shem E., George Benneh, Frank Place and Steven Atsu.1994. ‘Security of Tenure and Land Productivity in Kenya.’in Bruce and Migot-Adholla: 97-118.Mosqueira, Edgardo. 2007. ‘Urban Property Rights. Lessons and Impactsfrom WB Projects in LAC’ [draft].Nagarajan, G., C. David, and R. Meyer. 1992. ‘In<strong>for</strong>mal FinanceThrough Land Pawning Contracts: Evidence from <strong>the</strong> Philippines.’Journal of Development Studies 29(1): 93-107.Nagarajan, G., M. Quisumbing, and K. Otsuka. 1991. ‘Land pawningin <strong>the</strong> Philippines: an exploration into <strong>the</strong> consequences ofland re<strong>for</strong>m regulations.’ The Developing Economies 29/2:124-144.National Consultation Paper, Commission on Legal Empowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor (NCLEP), Ethiopia:Newman, Oscar. 1972. Defensible Space, New Y<strong>ork</strong>: MacmillanNielsen, Robin. 2006. ‘If he asks me to leave this place, I will go’.The Challenge to Secure Equitable Land Rights <strong>for</strong> RuralWomen’, in: de Soto and Cheneval 2006: 204-219.Nugent, Jeffrey B. and Robinson, James A. 2002. ‘Are EndowmentsFate?’ Centre <strong>for</strong> Economic Policy Research DiscussionPaper No. 3206.Okoth-Ogendo H. W. O. .1999. Land policy development in East Africa:a survey of recent trends, a regional overview paper <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>DFID w<strong>ork</strong>shop on „land rights and sustainable developmentin Sub-Saharan Africa’, Sunningdale Park ConferenceCentre, Berkshire, England, Great Britain, 16th-19 th February1999, at: http://www.oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/downloads/eafover.rtfOrganisation <strong>for</strong> Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD).2003. Land, Violent Confl ict and Development. Paris: OCED.Padilla, S. 2007. ‘Indigenous Peoples, Settlers and <strong>the</strong> PhilippineAncestral Domain Land Titling program.’ (Forthcoming inFrontier Encounters. University of Zurich Press).Palacin, José and Shelbourne, Robert C. 2005. ‘The Private HousingMarket in Eastern Europe and <strong>the</strong> CIS,’ UNECE DiscussionPaper Series 6, DecemberPalmer, David. 1998. ‘Security, Risk and Registration,’ Land Use Policy15/1: 83-94Panaritis, Elena. 2007. Prosperity Unbound. Building Property Marketswith Trust. Forword by Francis Fukuyama. New Y<strong>ork</strong>: PalgraveMacmillan.Payne, Geoffrey (ed.). 2002, ‘Land, Rights and Innovation: Improvingtenure security <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> urban poor’ ITDG Publishing London______. 1997. ‘Urban Land Tenure and Property Rights in DevelopingCountries. A Review’, IT Publications/ODA______. 2000. ‘Urban land tenure policy options: titles or rights?’Paper presented at <strong>the</strong> World Bank Urban Forum, Westfi eldsMarriott, Virginia, USA 03-05 April, 2000______. 2005. ‘Getting ahead of <strong>the</strong> game: A twin-track approach toimproving existing slums and reducing <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> futureslums.’ Environment and Urbanization Vol 17 No 1, April,pp. 135-145.Pottier, Johan. 2005. ‘Land Re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>for</strong> Peace? Rwanda’s 2005 Land<strong>Law</strong> in Context,’ Journal of Agrarian Change 6 (October2005).Prahalad, C.K. 2005. The Fortune at <strong>the</strong> Bottom of <strong>the</strong> Pyramid. EradicatingPoverty through Profi ts. Upper Saddle River: WhartonSchool Publishing.Prosterman, Roy. 2006. ‘Rural Property Right in China,’ in: de Soto/Cheneval 2006: 107-128.Quisumbing, A. and John Maluccio. 2000. ‘Intrahousehold Allocationsand Gender Relations: New Empirical Evidence from FourDeveloping Countries,’ Washington, DC: IFRPR.Rajan, R.G. 2005. ‘Failed states, vicious cycles, and a proposal,’mimeo, http://faculty.chicagogsb.edu/raghuram.rajan/research/.Ravna, Øyvind. 2006. ‘Recognition of Indigenous People’s Land Rightsthrough Modern Legislation. The Case of <strong>the</strong> Sami Peoplein Norway’, in: Norwegian Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Legal126


Empowerment, issue 2, Oslo: 65-90.Richards, Paul. (ed.). 2005. No Peace, No War. An Anthropology ofContemporary Armed Confl icts. Ohio University Press.Rolfes, Leonard. ‘A Framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> Land Market <strong>Law</strong> with <strong>the</strong> Poor inMind,’ in: Bruce et al. 2006: 107-142.Roll, Richard and Talbott, John. 2001. ‘Why Many Developing CountriesJust Aren’t,’ The Anderson School at UCLA, Finance W<strong>ork</strong>ingPaper No. 19-01, at:Sachs, Jeffrey. 2006. The End of Poverty: Economic Possibilities of ourTime. Penguin.Santiago, Astea. 2004. ‘<strong>Law</strong> and urban change in developing countries:<strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong> Philippines.’ In: Fernandes, E. andVarley, A. (eds.) Illegal Cities: <strong>Law</strong> and Urban Change inDeveloping Countries, Zed Books, London.Sattar, Sarosh and Shabih Mohib. 2007. ‘Tajikistan Cotton FarmlandPrivatization’, in: Coudouel et al. 2007: 453-488.Satterthwaite, David and D. Mitlin. 2004. Empowering Squatter Citizen.London: International Institute <strong>for</strong> Environment and Development.Safavian, Mehnaz, Heywood Fleisig, and Jevgenijs Steinbuks. 2006.Unlocking Dead Capital. Viewpoint, Note No. 307 (Washington,DC: World Bank).Siddiqui, Tasneem and M. Azhar Khan. 1994. ‘The Incremental DevelopmentScheme,’ Third World Planning Review 16/3:277-291.Singapore Housing and Development Board. Accessed at http://www.hdb.gov.sgSokoloff, K.L. and S.L. Engerman. 2000. ‘Institutions, factor endowments,and paths of development in <strong>the</strong> New World,’ Journalof Economic Perspectives, 14, 217-232.South African Institute of International Affairs. 2005. Special Feature:Unleashing Investment By Encouraging African Savings, at:www.saiia.org.za/modules.php?op=modloadandname=Newsandfi le=articleandsid=648 [seen 13.6.07].SPARC. 1995. ‘We <strong>the</strong> invisible revisited.’ Available at: http://www.sparcindia.orgStanfi eld, David and Peter Bloch. 2002. ‘USAID investments in landmarkets and property rights: Interim assessment basedon secondary sources’ Land Tenure Canter, University ofWisconsin.Steuteville, Robert. 2005. The New Urbanism: an alternative to modernautomobile-oriented planning and development, availableat: http://www.newurbanism.comStrickland, Richard S. 2004. ‘To Have and To Hold: Women’s Propertyand Inheritance Rights in <strong>the</strong> Context of HIV/AIDS in Sub-Saharan Africa,’ Washington, DC: ICRW.Tibaijuka, Anna Kajumulo. 2005. Report of <strong>the</strong> Fact-Finding Missionto Zimbabwe to assess <strong>the</strong> Scope and Impact of OperationMurambatsvina by <strong>the</strong> UN Special Envoy on Human SettlementsIssues in Zimbabwe. July 18.Tomlinson, Mary R. 2007. ‘The Development of a Low-Income HousingFinance Sector in South Africa: Have We Finally Found aWay Forward,’ Habitat International 31.Tongson, E. and McShane, T. 2004. ‘Securing Land Tenure <strong>for</strong> Biodiversity:Conservation in Sibuyan Island, Romblon, Philippines.”Paper presented at <strong>the</strong> UNU-WIDER and EGDIConference on Unlocking Human Potential: Linking <strong>the</strong>In<strong>for</strong>mal and Formal Sectors, Helsinki, Finland.UN-ESCAP. 1994. Municipal Land Management in Asia: A comparativestudy, Bankok, UN-ESCAP.United Nations Human Settlements Programme (UN-Habitat). 2004.‘Guidelines on How to Undertake a National Campaign <strong>for</strong>Secure Tenure,” UN-HABITAT website at: http://www.unhabitat.org/pmss/getPage.asp?page=bookViewandbook=1186.New Y<strong>ork</strong>: UN-HABITAT.UN-Habitat. 2006. ‘Progress Report on Removing DiscriminationAgainst Women in Respect of Property and InheritanceRights,” Nairobi.______. 2007. Enhancing Urban Safety and Security. Global Report onHuman Settlements.______. 2005. ‘Land tenure, housing rights and gender - nationaland urban framew<strong>ork</strong>’ <strong>Law</strong>, Land Tenure and Gender ReviewSeries: Latin America, Nairobi.______. 2005b. Financing Urban Shelter: Global Report on HumanSettlements. Nairobi.______. 2006. Analytical Perspective of Pro-Poor Slum UpgradingFramew<strong>ork</strong>s. Nairobi: United Nations Human SettlementsProgramme.______. 1991. The incremental development scheme: A case studyof Khuda ki Basti in Hyderabad, Pakistan, Nairobi, UN-HABITAT.United Nations. 1980. Report of <strong>the</strong> World Conference of <strong>the</strong> United NationsDecade <strong>for</strong> Women : Equality, Development and Peace,Doc A/Cof.94/35.United Nations Research Institute <strong>for</strong> Social Development (UNRISD).2006. ‘Land Tenure Re<strong>for</strong>m and Gender Equality,” Geneva,Switzerland.United States Agency <strong>for</strong> International Development (USAID). 2006.Land and Business Formalization <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor. A Strategic Overview Paper.______. 2007. Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. From Concepts toAssessments.Von Hoffman, Alexander. 1998. The Origins of American Housing Re<strong>for</strong>m.W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper 98-2. Joint Canter <strong>for</strong> Housing Studiesof Harvard University.Wallace, Jude and Williamson, 2006. ‘Building land markets,” LandUse Policy 23: 123-135.Wheeler, Samuel C. 1980. ‘Natural Property Rights as Body Rights,”Nous 14.Whitehead, Ann and Dzodzi Tsikata. 2003. ‘Policy Discourse on Women’sLand Rights in Sub-Saharan Africa: The Implicationsof <strong>the</strong> Return to <strong>the</strong> Customary,” Journal of AgrarianChange 3.Williams, Rhodri. 2005. ‘Post-Confl ict Property Restitution and RefugeeReturn in Bosnia and Herzegovina: Implications <strong>for</strong> InternationalStandard-Setting and Practice,’ New Y<strong>ork</strong> UniversityJournal of International <strong>Law</strong> and Politics 37: 441-553.Woodruff, Christopher. 2001. ‘Review of de Soto’s The Mystery of Capital,’Journal of Economic Literature 39: 1215-1223.Woolf, Virginia. 1938. Three Guineas.127


World Bank. 1993. ‘Housing: Enabling Markets to W<strong>ork</strong>,’ Housing policypaper, Washington, DC.______. 2001. ‘Land, Security, Property Rights and <strong>the</strong> Urban Poor:Twenty Five Years of World Bank Experience’. World BankBriefi ng Note 8, Washington, DC.______. 2002. World Development Report.______. 2003. ‘Land Policy <strong>for</strong> Pro-Poor Development’ World Bank,Washington, DC.______. 2003a. Housing: Enabling Markets to W<strong>ork</strong>. The World Bank.Washington, D.C.______. 2004. ‘Regional Study on Land Administration, Land Markets,and Collateralized Lending. East Asia and Pacifi c Region’World Bank, Washington, DC.______. 2004a. Water Resources Sector Strategy. Washington.______. 2006. ‘Afghanistan,’ Urban Policy Notes, Series 5.2,Washington, DC.World Business Council <strong>for</strong> Sustainable Development (WBCSD). 2005.Doing Business with <strong>the</strong> Poor. A Field Guide.World Health Organisation. 2000. The Urban Environment and Healthin a World of Increasing Globalization: Issues <strong>for</strong> DevelopingCountries. Bulletin Vol. 78. No.9. Geneva.Yu, S. and A. M. Karaos. 2004. ‘Establishing <strong>the</strong> role of communities ingovernance: <strong>the</strong> experience of <strong>the</strong> Homeless People’s FederationPhilippines.’ Environment and Urbanization 16(1):107-119.Yuen, Belinda. 2002. ‘Singapore,’ In: Agus, M.R./J Doling, J./Lee, D.S. (eds.), Housing Policy Systems in South and East Asia,Palgrave Macmillan______. 2004. Planning Singapore Growth <strong>for</strong> Better Living.’ In: MFreire and B Yuen (ed.) Enhancing Urban Management inEast Asia, Ashgate______. 2005. Squatters no more: Singapore Social Housing, WorldBank 3 rd Urban Research Symposium, Brasilia, Brazil.128


ChapterTHREETowards a GlobalSocial Contract:Labour Rights <strong>for</strong>Legal Empowermentof The Poor129


EXECUTIVE SUMMARYPurpose of this chapterChapter 3 is about labour rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> fight against poverty. Based on our review of employment andw<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, we present two essential messages.The first is that governments and internationalorganisations must address <strong>the</strong> decentw<strong>ork</strong> deficits of those who w<strong>ork</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mally, since<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, characterised by low productivity,low earnings and high risks, has beengrowing worldwide, emerging in many new guisesand in unexpected places. The second messageis one of hope. It is about <strong>the</strong> new departure ininternational development strategies, in which wefind broad coalitions being <strong>for</strong>med among governments,international organisations, trade unions,employers and non-governmental organisationsthat are willing to take on <strong>the</strong> challenge of creatingand implementing policies <strong>for</strong> decent w<strong>ork</strong>and empowerment of <strong>the</strong> poor.We describe this new departure in internationaldevelopment strategies as an emerging ‘GlobalSocial Contract’ and propose that <strong>the</strong> Commissionon Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor (sometimesreferred to by its acronym, CLEP) fur<strong>the</strong>rdevelop <strong>the</strong> concept into a framew<strong>ork</strong> integratingaccess to justice, property rights, labour rightsand business rights.130Labour rights, in<strong>for</strong>mal economy,empowerment and decent w<strong>ork</strong>: whatdo we mean?In Section 2, we define concepts used in this report.Labour rights include internationally agreedfundamental principles and rights at w<strong>ork</strong>, as wellas rights to social protection, income protection,w<strong>ork</strong>place safety, decent w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions andparticipation through representative organisationsof w<strong>ork</strong>ers, in national policy <strong>for</strong>a. Thisconcept also takes into account and supportscommitments and policies <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> creation of full,productive and freely-chosen employment andtraining. In<strong>for</strong>mal economy refers to economicactivities by w<strong>ork</strong>ers and economic units that are— in law or in practice — not covered or insufficientlycovered by <strong>for</strong>mal arrangements governingboth enterprise and employment relationships.Legal empowerment is that process throughwhich people are provided rights in an appropriatelegal framew<strong>ork</strong>, which <strong>the</strong>y can claim andunderstand, and which <strong>the</strong>y can find useful inimproving income and employment opportunities.It is a process recognised both <strong>for</strong>mally (legally)and in<strong>for</strong>mally (legitimately). We define decentw<strong>ork</strong> as that available to all men and women,


and grounded in conditions of freedom, securityand dignity. It has four pillars (a) fundamentalprinciples and rights at w<strong>ork</strong> under internationallabour standards; (b) employment and incomeopportunities; (c) social protection and socialsecurity, and (d) social dialogue and tripartism.In<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce: who are wetalking about?The vast majority of <strong>the</strong> poor earn <strong>the</strong>ir living in<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy where average earnings arelow, productivity poor, w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions hazardous,and risks high. Section 3 provides a globalpicture of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, highlighting itssize, segmentation, and vulnerabilities. Womendominate <strong>the</strong> most-disadvantaged categories ofin<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>, notably industrial outw<strong>ork</strong> andhome-based production. It is also in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy where child labour and bonded labourare most prevalent, and where indigenous andtribal peoples are marginalized largely by discrimination.Despite early predictions of its eventualdemise, <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy continues to grow.Poverty and labour rights: Towards aGlobal Social ContractSection 4 describes a new departure in <strong>the</strong>international community regarding labour rightsand <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy; it features threenoteworthy elements: <strong>the</strong> Fundamental Principlesand Rights at W<strong>ork</strong> from 1998; <strong>the</strong> DecentW<strong>ork</strong> Agenda, first introduced in 1999, and <strong>the</strong>2002 Strategy <strong>for</strong> Labour Rights in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy. These elements are gaining increasingsupport from a broad coalition of governments,international organisations, various employersand trade unions, as well as from non-governmentalorganisations.As part of ef<strong>for</strong>ts to achieve <strong>the</strong> MillenniumDevelopment Goals (MDGs), <strong>the</strong> 2005 WorldSummit of Heads of States agreed to make fulland productive employment and decent w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong> all a central objective of both national andinternational policies and national developmentand poverty reduction strategies. In 2006 thiswas followed by <strong>the</strong> UN Economic and SocialCouncil’s Ministerial Declaration, which emphasisedfull and productive employment and decentw<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> all as an end in itself and a means toachieve <strong>the</strong> MDGs. The Decent W<strong>ork</strong> Agenda has<strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e been accepted as a global aim; it nolonger remains an ILO agenda alone. Decent w<strong>ork</strong>has been declared a goal not only <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>malwage sector, but also <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.Growing recognition of <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> labour rightsto catalyse employment creation in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy, while protecting its w<strong>ork</strong>ers, has ledto an emerging global social contract, creating abroad agenda <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m and <strong>for</strong> empowerment.The economics of in<strong>for</strong>mality and <strong>the</strong>debate on labour regulationsFor <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor, it is not <strong>the</strong> absence ofeconomic activity that is <strong>the</strong> source of <strong>the</strong>irpoverty, but <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong>ir economic activities.The link between w<strong>ork</strong> of low quality, orproductivity, and poverty is clear: if people earnedmore, poverty would decline. In Section 5, wereview research on <strong>the</strong> role of labour regulationin setting economic and social goals, and wedraw two major conclusions. First, we suggestcaution in interpreting this research, particularly<strong>the</strong> cross-country studies. Caution shouldalso be exercised be<strong>for</strong>e translating <strong>the</strong> findingsinto country-level policy interventions withoutfirst considering country-specific conditions, <strong>the</strong>heterogeneity in <strong>the</strong> regulatory environment andemployment arrangements. Secondly, as a policyconclusion, we suggest a shift of focus from <strong>the</strong>prevailing ideological question on regulation-versus-deregulationto questions about how regula-131


tion can be used to promote decent w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor. The debate, we suggest, shouldfocus on <strong>the</strong> quality of regulation, and determining<strong>the</strong> right balance between security, supportivestructures, and flexibility in both <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal andin<strong>for</strong>mal economy.Principles and practices of labourrights and legal empowermentOur proposed strategy <strong>for</strong> legal empowerment,introduced in Section 6, is based oncommon core principles, while remaining flexibleto fit different economic, social and political conditions.It is participatory, inclusive and gendersensitive.Some of <strong>the</strong> principles are basic: <strong>the</strong>yinclude <strong>the</strong> need to combine promotion of changewith management of change, labour rights withproperty rights, and flexibility with security.Examples are presented to show that re<strong>for</strong>m isunderway; <strong>the</strong>y illustrate how different policiescan be used to provide w<strong>ork</strong>ing people with legalidentity (India, <strong>the</strong> Philippines and Thailand),voice and representation (India), social protection(Brazil, Chile, Ghana, India, Mexico, <strong>the</strong>Philippines), and new ways to resolve disputes(Tajikistan). They also show how different policiescan be used to improve <strong>the</strong> functioning of labourmarket institutions (Chile and Thailand), and tostrike a balance between protection and flexibilityin response to changing realities (Spain). Implicationsare drawn <strong>for</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r countries.Our recommendationsWe propose that <strong>the</strong> Commission accepts <strong>the</strong> followingrecommendations:Policy recommendationsStreng<strong>the</strong>n identity, voice, representation anddialogue: For <strong>the</strong> poor, labour and human capitalare <strong>the</strong> greatest assets, and <strong>the</strong>se must be effectivelyrecognised and supported to help <strong>the</strong> poorw<strong>ork</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir way out of poverty. First and <strong>for</strong>emost,<strong>the</strong> State must recognise <strong>the</strong>ir legal identity asw<strong>ork</strong>ers — <strong>the</strong> initial condition through which<strong>the</strong>y can engage in legal re<strong>for</strong>ms. Rights tofreedom of association and collective bargainingare also essential to streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> voice of <strong>the</strong>w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor and to facilitate <strong>the</strong>ir dialogue with<strong>for</strong>mal economy operators and public authorities.Improve <strong>the</strong> quality of labour regulation and <strong>the</strong>function of institutions: There is also need to improve<strong>the</strong> quality of labour regulation and to en<strong>for</strong>cefundamental principles and rights at w<strong>ork</strong>.The aim is to create synergies between protectionand productivity of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor and <strong>the</strong>ir assets.Critical and self-critical reviews of <strong>the</strong> qualityof institutions and regulations should examineimpacts on prosperity and labour protection.Support application of a minimum package oflabour rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy: Rightsshould be established in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy thatupholds <strong>the</strong> Declaration on Fundamental Principlesand Rights at W<strong>ork</strong> and <strong>the</strong> three crucial aspectsrelated to w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions: health and safetyat w<strong>ork</strong>, hours of w<strong>ork</strong>, and minimum income.Such a minimum floor <strong>for</strong> empowerment should berealistic and en<strong>for</strong>ceable. Progressive compliance— towards a fuller set of labour rights buildingupon this minimum floor - would be expected.Streng<strong>the</strong>n access to opportunities: Key to <strong>the</strong>legal empowerment process is <strong>the</strong> promotion ofchange and dynamism. This may be achieved by<strong>for</strong>ging links between private initiative and publicpolicy to encourage expansion of employment ina growing and inclusive economy. Opportunities<strong>for</strong> decent w<strong>ork</strong> are also advanced by provision<strong>for</strong> education, training and retraining, as well asby ef<strong>for</strong>ts to combat discrimination and promoteefficient labour markets.132


Support inclusive social protection: Universallyaccepted instruments, such as <strong>the</strong> UniversalDeclaration on Human Rights, recognise socialsecurity as a fundamental societal right <strong>for</strong> all.<strong>Law</strong>s, institutions and responsive mechanismsprotecting <strong>the</strong> poor from economic shocks, aswell as guaranteed access to medical care, healthinsurance, old age pensions, and social services,must be upheld. Social protection mechanismsmust be open to all types of w<strong>ork</strong>ers and notsolely on <strong>the</strong> basis of <strong>for</strong>mal evidence of employment.From a systemic perspective, rights to pensionsand health protection should be granted on<strong>the</strong> principle of universality to people as citizensra<strong>the</strong>r than as w<strong>ork</strong>ers.Promote legal empowerment as driver <strong>for</strong> genderequality: A key challenge is to ensure that ILOlabour standards, promoting equality of opportunityand treatment, are effectively extended to allw<strong>ork</strong>ing poor, especially women, in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy. This requires knowledge of wherew<strong>ork</strong>ing poor women are concentrated in <strong>the</strong>labour <strong>for</strong>ce, how <strong>the</strong>y are inserted into <strong>the</strong> globalproduction and with what consequences. Thereis a growing international movement, inspired by<strong>the</strong> Self-Employed Women’s Association (SEWA)of India, to increase <strong>the</strong> visibility and voice offemale in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers and to address <strong>the</strong>ir particulardisadvantages, in terms of opportunities,rights, protection and voice.Support legal empowerment <strong>for</strong> indigenouspeoples: Although indigenous peoples are disproportionatelyrepresented among <strong>the</strong> poor, <strong>the</strong>irneeds and priorities are generally not reflected inef<strong>for</strong>ts to combat poverty. ILO’s Indigenous andTribal Peoples Convention provides guidance andstrategies <strong>for</strong> legal empowerment with respect tolabour rights and protection of employment.Process recommendationsPromote national development framew<strong>ork</strong>s <strong>for</strong>legal empowerment and decent w<strong>ork</strong>: The decentw<strong>ork</strong> agenda is best defined at nationallevel through social dialogue. Its aim is to makeemployment a central goal of economic policies,recognising that progressive improvement in <strong>the</strong>quality of w<strong>ork</strong>, including labour rights and returnsto labour, is a main route out of poverty andof in<strong>for</strong>mality. Decent W<strong>ork</strong> Country Programmes(DWCPs) are major tools <strong>for</strong> driving this re<strong>for</strong>mprocess <strong>for</strong>ward in partnership with relevant nationaland international institutions.Mobilise <strong>the</strong> regional levels to support nationalre<strong>for</strong>m programmes: Re<strong>for</strong>m strategies addressingemployment and labour rights will need to beadapted to regional and local priorities. RegionalDevelopment Banks, regional organisations, like<strong>the</strong> African Union, as well as <strong>the</strong> UN and itsagencies, funds and programmes can be tappedas institutional champions <strong>for</strong> an integrated re<strong>for</strong>magenda on legal empowerment <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor.Mobilise <strong>the</strong> principal actors of <strong>the</strong> global system,particularly <strong>the</strong> World Bank and <strong>the</strong> ILO, to w<strong>ork</strong>better toge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong> decent w<strong>ork</strong>: The World Bank’sPoverty Reduction Strategies and ILO’s DWCPsare crucial instruments <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m. Legal empowermentthrough labour rights requires closecooperation between governments, employersand w<strong>ork</strong>ers, both nationally and locally. Capacitybuilding support from <strong>the</strong> leading global institutionswill streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> ability of traditionalsocial partners to reach out to w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. A key to a successful re<strong>for</strong>mprocess at national level is better policy coherenceat global level.Support voluntary initiatives <strong>for</strong> legal empowermentthrough labour rights: The ILO’s FundamentalPrinciples and Rights at W<strong>ork</strong> inspires many133


voluntary code-of-conduct initiatives. They arepursuing important strategies <strong>for</strong> motivating improvementsin <strong>the</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance of multinationalcorporations, and in encouraging businesses tobecome more sensitive to ethical consumer reactions.Such initiatives should be streng<strong>the</strong>nedand coherence between <strong>the</strong>m promoted so as toavoid dangers of proliferation. Voluntary initiativesshould be seen as stepping stones <strong>for</strong> legalempowerment, ra<strong>the</strong>r than a means to avoid legalobligations.Mobilise donor countries to promote legal empowermentand decent w<strong>ork</strong>: Donor countries havemany opportunities to support legal empowermentand <strong>the</strong> inclusion of a decent w<strong>ork</strong> agendain regional and national strategies.Promote better understanding of costs and benefitsof legal empowerment through decent w<strong>ork</strong>:Expected benefits of re<strong>for</strong>m from legal empowermentthrough decent w<strong>ork</strong> require fur<strong>the</strong>r study,particularly <strong>the</strong>ir effects on productivity andprosperity. The costs of policy initiatives to startand sustain re<strong>for</strong>m processes also need to be betterunderstood.Streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> statistical base <strong>for</strong> legal empowerment:Better national statistics and indicators onsize, composition, and contribution of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy would improve visibility and facilitateplanning, particularly <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>mulating policiespromoting Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor.Recommendations to fur<strong>the</strong>r develop<strong>the</strong> Global Social ContractThere is a tripartite consensus from employer,w<strong>ork</strong>er and government representatives on <strong>the</strong>need <strong>for</strong> a <strong>for</strong>mal and effective legal systemwhich guarantees all citizens and enterprises thatcontracts are honoured and upheld, <strong>the</strong> rule oflaw is respected and property rights are secured.This is a key condition not only <strong>for</strong> attractinginvestment, but also <strong>for</strong> generating certaintyand nurturing trust and fairness in society. 1 Thegrowing recognition of <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> labour rightsto catalyse employment creation in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy, while protecting its w<strong>ork</strong>ers, has led toan emerging global social contract; effectively,it is a broad agenda <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m and <strong>for</strong> empowerment.Labour rights, business rights, propertyrights and business rights, taken toge<strong>the</strong>r, can<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> basis of this new social contract.Five fundamental areas of action could underpin<strong>the</strong> new social contract: (1) Streng<strong>the</strong>n identity,voice, representation and dialogue; (2) Streng<strong>the</strong>nquality of labour regulation and effectiveen<strong>for</strong>cement of fundamental principles and rightsat w<strong>ork</strong>; (3) Support application of a minimumpackage of labour rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy;(4) Streng<strong>the</strong>n access to opportunities <strong>for</strong>decent w<strong>ork</strong>, education, training and retraining,while combating discrimination to ensure efficientlabour markets, and (5) Support inclusivesocial protection.We describe <strong>the</strong> new departure in internationaldevelopment strategies, centred on <strong>the</strong> DecentW<strong>ork</strong> Agenda, as a Global Social Contract andpropose that <strong>the</strong> Commission (or CLEP) fur<strong>the</strong>rdevelop <strong>the</strong> concept by integrating access tojustice, property rights, labour rights and businessrights into a framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor. Our proposals are firmly basedin <strong>the</strong> international human rights tradition, which<strong>the</strong> State, as primary duty bearer, is obliged toprotect and promote.Finally, we reflect on <strong>the</strong> words that <strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> conceptGlobal Social Contract. ‘Contract’ suggestsan emphasis on mutual responsibility. The state,<strong>for</strong> example, has a duty to protect, and citizenshave <strong>the</strong> right to protection. But <strong>the</strong>re are obliga-134


tions that follow from this, and employers andemployees are also tied by mutual obligations.Similarly, large businesses have a duty not toexploit smaller ones with which <strong>the</strong>y have productionor distribution ties. Our inclusion of <strong>the</strong> word‘global’ places a focus on <strong>the</strong> role and responsibilityof <strong>the</strong> actors at international, regional,national and local levels, while ‘social’ callsattention to <strong>the</strong> aim of this initiative, which is toimprove <strong>the</strong> social conditions of people in poorcountries. Importantly, we have placed <strong>the</strong> word‘towards’ be<strong>for</strong>e ‘a global social contract’ in <strong>the</strong>title of our chapter to emphasise development,process and time horizons.1. Introduction: Purpose ofour focus on Labour RightsThe Commission has identified <strong>the</strong> issue of labourrights as one of four elements of Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor. Almost half <strong>the</strong> world’s populationof 6 billion lives on less than US$2 a day,while a fifth survives on US$1 a day or less. Formost people mired in poverty, <strong>the</strong> only asset <strong>the</strong>yown is <strong>the</strong>ir own labour. The World Bank estimatesthat <strong>for</strong> over 70 percent of <strong>the</strong> poor, findingw<strong>ork</strong> — ei<strong>the</strong>r wage w<strong>ork</strong> or self-employment— is <strong>the</strong> main pathway out of poverty; 2 but <strong>the</strong>stark reality, according to <strong>the</strong> ILO, is that some500 million of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor are currently unableto achieve this goal.In<strong>for</strong>mality in <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce has always beenpredominant in developing countries — but itis also growing in developed economies. For <strong>the</strong>poor, in<strong>for</strong>mal employment is <strong>the</strong> predominant<strong>for</strong>m of employment, in which <strong>the</strong>y have no legalidentity as entrepreneurs or as w<strong>ork</strong>ers. Also,<strong>the</strong> wider policy environment and institutionallandscape, including systems of legal and socialprotection, are biased towards <strong>for</strong>mal incorporatedfirms and <strong>for</strong>mal organised w<strong>ork</strong>ers. Often,<strong>the</strong> poor are shut out of <strong>the</strong> legally recognisedsystems that would allow <strong>the</strong>m to benefit from<strong>the</strong>ir hard w<strong>ork</strong>. They are mostly excluded from<strong>the</strong> legal mechanisms that protect <strong>the</strong>ir assetsrelated to property or labour. They lack access toa fully-functioning justice system that protects<strong>the</strong>ir rights regardless of status in life.135The ILO notes that in<strong>for</strong>mality is mainly a governanceissue; 3 it is traced to laws and institutionalframew<strong>ork</strong>s that are not responsive to <strong>the</strong>conditions in which <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor have alwaysbeen or are increasingly found. The boundaries oflaws and institutional framew<strong>ork</strong>s remain unyieldingto <strong>the</strong> growing number of poor who are found


outside <strong>the</strong>ir protective reach. The World Bankhas shown that, while in<strong>for</strong>mality is strongly correlatedwith low productivity and a high degree ofpoverty, 4 governance and quality of regulation canplay an important role in engendering prosperityand protection <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce.Our aim is to suggest how to address <strong>the</strong> viciouscircle of in<strong>for</strong>mality, lack of legal protection, andpoverty. Our point of departure is that poverty isboth a market failure and a public policy failure,which <strong>the</strong> international community has begun torecognise. Within <strong>the</strong> past 10 years, <strong>for</strong> example,attempts have been made to obtain global consensuson <strong>the</strong> Fundamental Principles and Rightsof W<strong>ork</strong>, and to gain widespread endorsement of<strong>the</strong> Decent W<strong>ork</strong> Agenda. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong>re isevidence of growing recognition of <strong>the</strong> need to extendlabour rights to <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy.These are strategic priorities and <strong>the</strong>y constitute<strong>the</strong> three pillars of an emerging global social contractwith wide support in <strong>the</strong> international community,including governments in rich and poorcountries, <strong>the</strong> UN family, international financialinstitutions, employers, trade unions, and NGOs.This chapter contains seven sections. Section2 defines labour rights, in<strong>for</strong>mal economy,empowerment and decent w<strong>ork</strong>, while Section 3explains who we are talking about — <strong>the</strong> size andcomposition of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce and <strong>the</strong>many segments found <strong>the</strong>rein. Next, Section 4highlights new initiatives <strong>for</strong> labour rights in <strong>the</strong>fight against poverty and describes <strong>the</strong> internationalconsensus that has developed around thisnew agenda — Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorthrough labour rights. Following this, Section 5examines <strong>the</strong> economic rationale <strong>for</strong> legal empowermentthrough labour rights, and summarizes<strong>the</strong> economic debates surrounding labourregulations. In Section 6 we provide recommendationson <strong>the</strong> principles and practices of re<strong>for</strong>m,as well as case materials on selected countryexperiences reflecting appropriate responses to<strong>the</strong> extension of labour rights and standards toall <strong>for</strong>ms of employment or w<strong>ork</strong> arrangements.Finally, Section 7 sets out our recommendationson policies and processes needed to carry out <strong>the</strong>proposed plan of action.Our recommendations are aimed at taking thisagenda <strong>for</strong>ward in a manner coordinated with<strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups of <strong>the</strong> Commission onLegal Empowerment that are focused on accessto justice, property rights and business rights. Weargue that is it important to merge <strong>the</strong> free marketapproach with a human rights approach bycombining: (a) promotion of economic growth toimprove productivity and job creation stimulatedby competition, specialisation and free trade, and(b) management of economic growth to obtainwidely-shared prosperity through <strong>the</strong> advancementof decent w<strong>ork</strong>, social dialogue, inclusion,and social protection of all w<strong>ork</strong>ers.136


2. Labour Rights, In<strong>for</strong>malEconomy, Empowermentand Decent W<strong>ork</strong>: What dowe mean?In this section we define <strong>the</strong> key terms andconcepts that underpin our discussions; namely,labour rights, in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, legal empowermentand decent w<strong>ork</strong>.Labour RightsThe concept of labour rights includes <strong>the</strong> internationallyagreed-upon Fundamental Principles andRights at W<strong>ork</strong> 5 as well as rights to social protectionand income protection, w<strong>ork</strong>place safety,decent w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions and <strong>the</strong> participationthrough representative organisations in nationalpolicy <strong>for</strong>ums. This concept also takes into accountand supports commitments and policies <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> creation of full, productive and freely chosenemployment as well as w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce development.These rights can be expressed through differentmechanisms at <strong>the</strong> international, national and locallevels, such as those relating to internationallabour standards, national labour law, nationaland local regulations and labour agreementsbetween employers and w<strong>ork</strong>ers. Socially responsiblecorporations and o<strong>the</strong>r organisations mayalso express <strong>the</strong>m in a voluntary way.In<strong>for</strong>mal EconomyThe in<strong>for</strong>mal economy is defined as comprising‘all economic activities by w<strong>ork</strong>ers andeconomic units that are — in law or in practice— not covered or insufficiently covered by <strong>for</strong>malarrangements’ regulating both enterprise and employmentrelationships. 6 In<strong>for</strong>mal employment 7consists of two broad categories, <strong>the</strong> self-employedin in<strong>for</strong>mal (small unregistered) enterprisesand wagew<strong>ork</strong>ers in in<strong>for</strong>mal (unprotected)jobs, including disguised wagew<strong>ork</strong>ers. Underthis expanded international statistical framew<strong>ork</strong>,<strong>the</strong> specific criteria used <strong>for</strong> determining whatis (or is not) an in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprise and what is(or is not) an in<strong>for</strong>mal job are set by countries,including: what size of enterprise and what typeof registration should be used <strong>for</strong> determiningwhat is an in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprise; and what type ofcontract or social protection coverage should beused <strong>for</strong> determining what is an in<strong>for</strong>mal job.Legal EmpowermentLegal empowerment is defined as a processthrough which people are provided rightsin an appropriate legal framew<strong>ork</strong>, which <strong>the</strong>yunderstand, can claim, find useful in improving<strong>the</strong>ir income and livelihoods, and which arerecognised both <strong>for</strong>mally (legally) and in<strong>for</strong>mally(legitimately). Thus, legal empowerment requiresthat in<strong>for</strong>mation is available and appropriateinstitutions are established to ensure that commercialand employment contracts are respected,property titles and businesses are registered,and access to social protection and justice is athand. By this, people are able to engage publicand private sector agents and participate in fullyfunctioning market institutions.All too often, <strong>the</strong> poor do not know of, or are notable to understand regulations. Moreover, <strong>the</strong>ydo not have contracts, and lack resort to disputemediation. The absence of in<strong>for</strong>mation and ofappropriate institutions curtails <strong>the</strong> exercise ofchoice. Yet, <strong>the</strong> existence of choice, <strong>the</strong> exerciseof choice, and <strong>the</strong> achievement of choice in <strong>the</strong>different domains of a person’s life (includingw<strong>ork</strong>) lie at <strong>the</strong> heart of legal empowerment. 8It is important to emphasise that empowerment isboth a process and a goal. It is a process wherebykey stakeholders are involved in framing coherent137


and sustainable solutions and people are engagedin a continuous ef<strong>for</strong>t to find responses to evolvingissues. However, it is a goal in that socialdialogue and participation is an objective in andof itself — one of <strong>the</strong> four pillars of decent w<strong>ork</strong>as defined below.According to one definition, empowerment isbased on four conditions, namely, access toin<strong>for</strong>mation, systems of accountability, venues <strong>for</strong>inclusion/participation and local organisationalcapacity. 9In <strong>the</strong> domain of labour rights, empowerment issecured when <strong>the</strong> fundamental principles andrights at w<strong>ork</strong> are respected. These so-called‘enabling rights’ can be considered avenues toempowerment. 10 They constitute <strong>the</strong> basic rightto participation and freedom of choice in <strong>the</strong>arena of w<strong>ork</strong> that everyone should enjoy.Decent W<strong>ork</strong>The International Labour Organisation introduced<strong>the</strong> notion of decent w<strong>ork</strong> in 1999. 11 Its premise:opportunities <strong>for</strong> all women and men to w<strong>ork</strong> inconditions of freedom, security and dignity, hasbecome a global goal endorsed by <strong>the</strong> internationalcommunity. Decent w<strong>ork</strong> rests on four pillars:(a) fundamental principles and rights at w<strong>ork</strong> andinternational labour standards; (b) employmentand income opportunities; (c) social protectionand social security; and (d) social dialogue andtripartism.3. In<strong>for</strong>mality and Poverty:Whom are we talkingabout? What is <strong>the</strong>iridentity?This section presents an overview of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy, including its size and structure as wellas <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ers in it. The Commission (CLEP) haschosen to focus on <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy becauseof <strong>the</strong> strong link between in<strong>for</strong>mality and poverty.Also, as <strong>the</strong> World Bank has found in a studyof 75 countries, in<strong>for</strong>mality is correlated with lowproductivity and low GDP growth. 12According to ILO estimates, <strong>the</strong>re are some 500million w<strong>ork</strong>ing people living in households thatearn less than US$1 per capita per day. The vastmajority of <strong>the</strong>se ‘w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor’ earn <strong>the</strong>ir livingin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. The in<strong>for</strong>mal economyis associated not only with low productivity butalso low earnings, poor w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions, highrisks, and little (if any) legal or social protections.While <strong>the</strong>re is not a complete overlap betweenw<strong>ork</strong>ing in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy and being poor,or w<strong>ork</strong>ing in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy and escapingpoverty, <strong>the</strong> link between in<strong>for</strong>mality and povertyis quite significant and stark.What follows is a summary of recent estimates of<strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy in 25 developingcountries 13 and recent analyses of changesin in<strong>for</strong>mal employment over time in 20 of <strong>the</strong>secountries. 14 Official national data were used toestimate in<strong>for</strong>mal employment in each of <strong>the</strong>countries. 15Size and significance in developingcountriesIn<strong>for</strong>mal employment, broadly defined, comprisesone-half to three-quarters of non-agricultural em-138


ployment in developing countries: specifically, 47percent in <strong>the</strong> Middle East and North Africa; 51percent in Latin America; 71 percent in Asia, and72 percent in sub-Saharan Africa. If South Africais excluded, <strong>the</strong> share of in<strong>for</strong>mal employment innon-agricultural employment rises to 78 percentin sub-Saharan Africa; and if comparable datawere available <strong>for</strong> countries (o<strong>the</strong>r than India), inSouth Asia, <strong>the</strong> regional average <strong>for</strong> Asia wouldlikely be much higher.Some countries include in<strong>for</strong>mal employmentin agriculture in <strong>the</strong>ir estimates. Thissignificantly increases <strong>the</strong> proportion of in<strong>for</strong>malemployment: from 83 percent of non-agriculturalemployment to 93 percent of total employment inIndia; from 55 to 62 percent in Mexico, and from28 to 34 percent in South Africa. 16The two main segments of in<strong>for</strong>mal employment,classified by employment status, are <strong>the</strong> self-employedand <strong>the</strong> wagew<strong>ork</strong>ers. The self-employedinclude employers, or owner-operators of in<strong>for</strong>malenterprises who hire o<strong>the</strong>rs; own-account w<strong>ork</strong>ers,or owner-operators in single-person units orfamily businesses/farms who do not hire o<strong>the</strong>rs,and unpaid contributing family w<strong>ork</strong>ers, whoare family w<strong>ork</strong>ers in family businesses or farmswithout pay.The wagew<strong>ork</strong>er segment consists largely ofin<strong>for</strong>mal employees — those who are unprotectedin <strong>the</strong>ir w<strong>ork</strong> with a known employer that couldbe an in<strong>for</strong>mal or <strong>for</strong>mal enterprise, a contractingagency, or a household; casual wage w<strong>ork</strong>er, orthose wage w<strong>ork</strong>ers with no fixed employer whosell <strong>the</strong>ir labour on a daily or seasonal basis, andindustrial outw<strong>ork</strong>ers, who are sub-contractedto produce <strong>for</strong> a piece-rate from <strong>the</strong>ir homes orsmall w<strong>ork</strong>shops.Composition of <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal EconomyIn all developing regions, self-employment comprisesa greater share of in<strong>for</strong>mal employment(outside of agriculture) than wage employment:specifically, self-employment represents 70percent of in<strong>for</strong>mal employment in sub-SaharanAfrica, 62 percent in North Africa, 60 percent inLatin America, and 59 percent in Asia. In China,it is estimated that between 1990 and 2004,urban in<strong>for</strong>mal employment increased by 125.55million people, which was 133 percent of allincreased employment. 17 Excluding South Africa,where black-owned businesses were prohibitedduring <strong>the</strong> apar<strong>the</strong>id era and have only recentlybegun to be recognised and reported, <strong>the</strong> share ofself-employment in in<strong>for</strong>mal employment increasedto 81 percent in sub-Saharan Africa.Self-employment represents nearly one-third oftotal non-agricultural employment worldwide. It isless important in developed countries (12 percentof total non-agricultural employment) than indeveloping countries where it comprises as muchas 53 percent of non-agricultural employment insub-Saharan Africa, 44 percent in Latin America,32 percent in Asia, and 31 percent in NorthAfrica.In<strong>for</strong>mal wage employment, including disguisedwage employment, is also significant in <strong>the</strong>developing world: comprising 30 to 40 percent ofin<strong>for</strong>mal employment (outside of agriculture). 18Home-based w<strong>ork</strong>ers and street vendors are twoof <strong>the</strong> largest sub-groups of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce:with home-based w<strong>ork</strong>ers being <strong>the</strong> morenumerous but street vendors <strong>the</strong> more visible of<strong>the</strong> two. Toge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y represent 10-25 percentof <strong>the</strong> non-agricultural w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce in developingcountries and over five percent of <strong>the</strong> total w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>cein developed countries.139


Segmentation in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal LabourMarket 19Available evidence suggests that <strong>the</strong>re is markedsegmentation within in<strong>for</strong>mal labour marketsin terms of average earnings across <strong>the</strong> differentemployment statuses. Specifically, in<strong>for</strong>malemployers have <strong>the</strong> highest earnings on average;followed by <strong>the</strong>ir employees and in<strong>for</strong>mal employeesof <strong>for</strong>mal firms; <strong>the</strong>n own account operatorsfollowed by casual wage w<strong>ork</strong>ers, and industrialoutw<strong>ork</strong>ers: see Figure 1. An inverse hierarchy isobserved <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> risk of being from a poor household:employers are least likely to be from poorhouseholds and, especially if <strong>the</strong>y are <strong>the</strong> primarybreadwinners, industrial outw<strong>ork</strong>ers are <strong>the</strong> mostlikely to be from poor households.In Tunisia, <strong>for</strong> example, in<strong>for</strong>mal employers earnfour times <strong>the</strong> minimum wage and over two times(2.2) <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal wage. Their employees earnroughly <strong>the</strong> minimum wage, while industrial outw<strong>ork</strong>ers— mostly women home-w<strong>ork</strong>ers — earnless than one-third (30 percent) of <strong>the</strong> minimumwage. In Columbia and India, in<strong>for</strong>mal employersearn four-to-five times <strong>the</strong> minimum wage, whileown account operators earn only one-and-a-halftimes <strong>the</strong> minimum wage. 20Research findings suggest that it is difficult tomove up <strong>the</strong>se segments due to structural barriers(state, market, and social) and/or cumulativedisadvantages. Many w<strong>ork</strong>ers, especially women,remain trapped in <strong>the</strong> lower-earning and morerisky segments.Figure 1 Segmentation of <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy: By Sex, Average Earnings and Poverty RiskPoverty RiskAverage EarningsSegmentation by SexLOWHIGHEmployersPredominantly MenIn<strong>for</strong>mal EmployeesOwn Account OperatorsMen and WomenCasual Day LabourersUnpaid Family W<strong>ork</strong>ersPredominantlyWomenNote: The in<strong>for</strong>mal economy may also be segmented by race, ethnicity, caste or religion.Source: Chen et al 2004, 2005.140


Box 1 Different Categories of In<strong>for</strong>mal W<strong>ork</strong>ersand Corresponding ChallengesCategories of W<strong>ork</strong>ersEmployees of in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprisesCasual day labourersHomew<strong>ork</strong>ers or Home-based producersDomestic w<strong>ork</strong>ersContract labour <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal fi rmsMigrant labourersConceptual/Practical ChallengesAbility of employers to complyCost of complianceZero-cost of non-complianceEpisodic/seasonal w<strong>ork</strong>No fixed employerAmbiguous employment status:nei<strong>the</strong>r dependent nor independentAmbiguous relationship with contractor:commercial vs. employmentUncertainty as to who is principally responsible:contractor or lead firm?Household as employerMultiple employersUncertainty re who is principally responsible:contractor or <strong>for</strong>mal firm?Intersection of immigration status/regime and labour status/regimeSource: Martha Chen, ‘Labour standards and in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers: The nature of <strong>the</strong> challenge.’ Paper prepared <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Commission on Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor, November 2006.Ano<strong>the</strong>r type of segmentation is based on differencesbetween women and men within <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy reflecting gender norms whichinfluence both <strong>the</strong> supply of and <strong>the</strong> demand <strong>for</strong>labour. As a general rule in developing countries,men tend to be over-represented in <strong>the</strong> top segmentsof <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy; women tend tobe over-represented in <strong>the</strong> bottom segment.More specifically, relatively high shares of in<strong>for</strong>malemployers are men and relatively high sharesof industrial outw<strong>ork</strong>ers are women. In India, <strong>for</strong>example, 6 percent of in<strong>for</strong>mal employers, 19percent of own account operators, 16 percent ofin<strong>for</strong>mal wage w<strong>ork</strong>ers, and 59 percent of industrialoutw<strong>ork</strong>ers are women. 21 These stylised factsare depicted graphically in Figure 1.A legal empowerment agenda <strong>for</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy must take into account <strong>the</strong> differentcategories of in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers and <strong>the</strong> specificrealities of <strong>the</strong>ir w<strong>ork</strong> arrangements. In Box1, below, <strong>the</strong>re are illustrations of <strong>the</strong> conceptualand practical challenges in considering labourrights and protections <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> different categoriesof in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers. A proper understanding of<strong>the</strong> nuances and challenges should lead not onlyto appropriate legal responses but also to a widerset of policy tools and institutional strategies. 22141


In<strong>for</strong>malisation of Labour MarketsThere is a widespread assumption that <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy is counter-cyclical: that is, itexpands during economic down turns and contractsduring periods of economic growth. To besure, empirical evidence from a set of developedand developing countries indicates that <strong>the</strong> levelof in<strong>for</strong>mal employment, taking self-employmentas a proxy indicator, decreases when GDPper capita goes up and vice versa. 23 However, asshown above, <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy is made upof both self-employed and wage w<strong>ork</strong>ers, <strong>the</strong>rebydemonstrating limitations to <strong>the</strong> use of self-employmentalone as a proxy indicator. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore,<strong>the</strong> co-relationship between in<strong>for</strong>mal employmentand growth is not straight<strong>for</strong>ward. Recent analysesof data over time from different developingcountries suggest a more complex and dynamicrelationship between in<strong>for</strong>mality and economicgrowth. While economic downturns are almost invariablyassociated with an expansion of employmentin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy (due to <strong>the</strong> growthin survival activities), steady rates of economicgrowth may be accompanied, not by a reduction,but actually an expansion of employmentin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. This is because duringeconomic upswings, certain <strong>for</strong>ms of in<strong>for</strong>malemployment may expand, such as <strong>the</strong> more entrepreneurialsmall firms as well as sub-contractedand outsourced activities linked to <strong>the</strong> globalproduction system. 24 This may well demonstratethat increasingly <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy is enteringinto a symbiotic relationship with <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal,where <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mer makes use of <strong>the</strong> latter toimprove profits and growth strategies, perhapseven to avoid respecting labour standards andregulations. In <strong>the</strong>se countries, it was only aftera sustained period of higher levels of growth thataggregate in<strong>for</strong>malisation declined. 25 This importantfinding is fur<strong>the</strong>r elaborated in Box 2.Box 2 Relationship betweenin<strong>for</strong>mality and growth:Cross-country evidenceConsider <strong>the</strong> findings from 20 countries in Asia,Africa, and Latin America at two points in time— generally in <strong>the</strong> 1980s and <strong>the</strong> 1990s. Foreach of <strong>the</strong> countries, <strong>the</strong> rate of change in in<strong>for</strong>malisationis compared to <strong>the</strong> average per capitaGDP growth (Heintz and Pollin 2003). Most of <strong>the</strong>countries (14 out of 20) experienced growth in in<strong>for</strong>malisation,while four experienced a decline and twoexperienced little, if any, change. What is interestingto note is that in<strong>for</strong>malisation increased in threecountries with respectable per capita growth rates(>2 percent) and declined in two countries with poorper capita growth rates (


In North American, European Union, and o<strong>the</strong>rOECD countries, available evidence suggeststhat non-standard employment is on <strong>the</strong> rise.The term ‘non-standard w<strong>ork</strong>’ as commonly used,includes: a) jobs entailing an employment arrangementthat diverges from regular, year-round,full-time employment with a single employer butwithout security; and b) self-employment, withor without employees. (Carré and Herranz 2002.)The common categories of non-standard wagew<strong>ork</strong> are temporary, fixed-term and part-time.Increasingly, inter-firm sub-contracted w<strong>ork</strong> in<strong>the</strong> service sector (<strong>for</strong> example, janitorial servicesand home care) and <strong>the</strong> manufacturing sector(garment making, electronic assembly) is alsoincluded.What follows is a brief summary of trends in threecategories of non-standard w<strong>ork</strong> — part-timew<strong>ork</strong>, temporary w<strong>ork</strong>, and self-employment — inEurope, including differences by sex. (Carré andHerranz 2002, Carré 2006.)Part-Time W<strong>ork</strong>: Since <strong>the</strong> early 1970s, <strong>the</strong>rehas been a marked growth in <strong>the</strong> proportion ofpart-time w<strong>ork</strong>ers in total employment. By 1998,part-time w<strong>ork</strong>ers accounted <strong>for</strong> 16 percent oftotal employment in EU countries and 14 percentof total employment in OECD countries.Temporary Employment: For <strong>the</strong> EU as a whole,and in a majority of EU nations, <strong>the</strong> share ofw<strong>ork</strong>ers in temporary employment, including bothdirect hire and agency hire, increased from <strong>the</strong>mid-1980s to <strong>the</strong> late 1990s. By 1998, temporaryemployment accounted <strong>for</strong> around10 percent of total employment in EU countries.Self-Employment: Self-employment, includingboth employers and own account w<strong>ork</strong>ers, has increasedin many OECD countries over <strong>the</strong> past 25years. 26 Indeed, outside of agriculture, self-employmenthas grown at a faster rate than total employmentin 14 (out of 24) OECD countries wheredata were available. Also, as self-employment hasbeen growing, so has <strong>the</strong> share of own accountself-employment within total self-employment. Asa result, in OECD countries today, more self-employedpersons are own account w<strong>ork</strong>ers, ra<strong>the</strong>rthan employers.In addition to <strong>the</strong>se common <strong>for</strong>ms of non-standardw<strong>ork</strong> in OECD countries, <strong>the</strong>re are o<strong>the</strong>r<strong>for</strong>ms of non-standard w<strong>ork</strong> — notably, casualday labour, industrial outw<strong>ork</strong>, and o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>ms ofsub-contracted w<strong>ork</strong> — <strong>for</strong> which data are not soreadily available.In sum, <strong>the</strong> purely counter-cyclical model of in<strong>for</strong>malitydoes not hold. At least in <strong>the</strong> short term,countries demonstrate significant variation in <strong>the</strong>irpatterns of in<strong>for</strong>malisation even under conditionsof steady economic growth. Also, different segmentsof <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy demonstrate substantialvariation in <strong>the</strong>ir cyclical patterns. Certainsegments of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy expand duringdownturns in <strong>the</strong> economy: particularly survivalactivities and sub-contracted activities <strong>for</strong> firmstrying to cope with <strong>the</strong> downturn. Certain o<strong>the</strong>rsegments of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy expand duringupturns in <strong>the</strong> economy: notably, dynamic independententerprises and sub-contracted activitieslinked to global value chains.Gendered patternsIn<strong>for</strong>malisation of Labour Markets by SexThe last two decades have seen a marked increasein women’s labour <strong>for</strong>ce participation: most significantlyin <strong>the</strong> Americas and Western Europe andmore modestly in Sub-Saharan Africa, Sou<strong>the</strong>astAsia, and East Asia. 27 Only in two regions — EasternEurope and South Asia — has <strong>the</strong> women’slabour <strong>for</strong>ce participation rate actually fallen. Themarked increase in women’s labour <strong>for</strong>ce partici-143


pation worldwide has given rise to <strong>the</strong> notion of<strong>the</strong> ‘feminisation of <strong>the</strong> labour <strong>for</strong>ce’. But thisnotion has been defined and used in two distinctways. First, to refer to <strong>the</strong> situation in which <strong>the</strong>ratio of women’s labour <strong>for</strong>ce participation rate tomen’s labour <strong>for</strong>ce participation rate increases overtime. Second, to refer to a situation in which <strong>the</strong>structure of <strong>the</strong> labour <strong>for</strong>ce itself is ‘feminised’:that is, when jobs take on features associated withwomen’s w<strong>ork</strong> such as low pay, drudgery, uncertainty,and precariousness. 28Whe<strong>the</strong>r or not <strong>the</strong>re is a causal link between <strong>the</strong>increase in women’s labour <strong>for</strong>ce participationand <strong>the</strong> growing precariousness or in<strong>for</strong>mality ofw<strong>ork</strong> is not clear — and has been hotly debated.The pervasive segmentation of labour marketsby gender, which we discussed above, suggeststhat women’s labour did not simply substitute <strong>for</strong>men’s labour. Ra<strong>the</strong>r, that <strong>the</strong>re has been someparallel process at w<strong>ork</strong> creating low-paid andpoor quality in<strong>for</strong>mal employment opportunities<strong>for</strong> (primarily) women. 29Estimates of changes over time in <strong>the</strong> degree ofin<strong>for</strong>malisation within <strong>the</strong> female and male labour<strong>for</strong>ce are not available. However, we have seenabove that growth in certain <strong>for</strong>ms of in<strong>for</strong>malemployment — notably, sub-contracted w<strong>ork</strong>linked to <strong>the</strong> global production system — expandsduring periods of economic growth, especiallywhen growth is driven by trade and financialliberalisation. What is important to note hereis that women w<strong>ork</strong>ers tend to be overrepresentedin global production systems, at least in <strong>the</strong> earlystages of trade liberalisation when a premium isplaced on export-oriented light manufacturingand low-skilled (and low-paid) w<strong>ork</strong>ers. 30In<strong>for</strong>mal Employment in Developing CountriesIn<strong>for</strong>mal employment is generally a larger sourceof employment <strong>for</strong> women than <strong>for</strong> men in <strong>the</strong>developing world. O<strong>the</strong>r than in <strong>the</strong> Middle Eastand North Africa, where 42 percent of womenw<strong>ork</strong>ers (and 48 percent of male w<strong>ork</strong>ers) arein in<strong>for</strong>mal employment, 60 percent or more ofwomen non-agricultural w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> developingworld are in<strong>for</strong>mally employed. Among non-agriculturalw<strong>ork</strong>ers, in sub-Saharan Africa, 84 percentof women w<strong>ork</strong>ers are in<strong>for</strong>mally employedcompared to 63 percent of male w<strong>ork</strong>ers; in LatinAmerica, 58 percent of women w<strong>ork</strong>ers comparedto 48 percent of men; and in Asia, 73 percent ofwomen w<strong>ork</strong>ers compared to 70 percent of malew<strong>ork</strong>ers.Non-Standard Employment in DevelopedCountriesIn virtually all EU and OECD countries, <strong>the</strong> incidenceof part-time w<strong>ork</strong> is much higher amongwomen than men: in some countries it is twice ashigh. By 1998, women represented 82 percentof all part-time w<strong>ork</strong>ers in EU countries. Fur<strong>the</strong>r,rates of part-time w<strong>ork</strong> are high <strong>for</strong> women, butnot men, in <strong>the</strong>ir prime w<strong>ork</strong>ing years.Temporary employment, like part-time w<strong>ork</strong>,is primarily a female phenomenon, although<strong>the</strong>re is wide variation among EU countries. Inall countries except Austria, <strong>the</strong> incidence oftemporary employment among females is higherthan among all w<strong>ork</strong>ers. And, like part-time w<strong>ork</strong>,temporary employment is concentrated in <strong>the</strong> service-producingindustries. Interestingly, womenaccount <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> majority of agency temps incountries where such employment concentratesin services, while men account <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> majority ofagency temps in countries where such employmentconcentrates in manufacturing and construction.Effectively, ‘<strong>the</strong> gender composition ofemployment mirrors that of <strong>the</strong> sectors in whichtemporary agency assignments take place.’ 31In 1997, women comprised one in three of144


self-employed persons in OECD countries and<strong>the</strong>ir proportion is growing. For EU countries asa whole, <strong>the</strong> incidence of own-account w<strong>ork</strong> isgreater <strong>for</strong> men (11 percent) than <strong>for</strong> women (7percent). But, in some countries, a higher proportionof women than men are own-account w<strong>ork</strong>ers.Age is a factor in own-account w<strong>ork</strong>: thoseaged 45 and above are more likely than youngerpersons to be w<strong>ork</strong>ing on <strong>the</strong>ir own account. 32Indigenous and Tribal PeoplesFinally, one specific group in society that hasoften suffered from abject poverty and profounddiscrimination consists of indigenous and tribalpeoples. It is estimated that <strong>the</strong>re are 350 millionindigenous and tribal peoples (ITPs) representing5000 ethnic groups. While <strong>the</strong>y representfive percent of <strong>the</strong> world’s population, <strong>the</strong>y account<strong>for</strong> 15 percent of <strong>the</strong> world’s poor. Poverty,inequality, and various types of injustices haveplagued ethnic societies around <strong>the</strong> world. 33The ILO has defined indigenous and tribal peoplesas those who have (a) traditional lifestyles,(b) culture, economic conditions and way of lifethat is different from <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r segments of <strong>the</strong>national population (e.g., in <strong>the</strong>ir ways of makinga living, language and customs), and (c) <strong>the</strong>irown social organisation and traditional customsand laws. Indigenous peoples are, fur<strong>the</strong>rmore,distinguished from tribal peoples by <strong>the</strong> fact that<strong>the</strong>y live in historical continuity in a certain area,or be<strong>for</strong>e o<strong>the</strong>rs occupied or came to <strong>the</strong>ir area. 34The definition of ‘indigenous’ as provided by <strong>the</strong>United Nations shares features with that providedby ILO: it highlights <strong>the</strong> ‘historical continuity of<strong>the</strong>se peoples with pre-colonial societies; <strong>the</strong>irstrong attachment to <strong>the</strong>ir traditional territories;<strong>the</strong>ir distinct social, economic and political institutionsas well as distinct languages and beliefs;<strong>the</strong>ir non-dominant position in national societiesand <strong>the</strong>ir wish to identify <strong>the</strong>mselves as differentfrom <strong>the</strong> rest of society.’ 35At <strong>the</strong> root of <strong>the</strong> poverty and social exclusionfacing ITPs everywhere is discrimination. Whe<strong>the</strong>rimplicitly or explicitly, ITPs have faced discriminationaimed at wiping out <strong>the</strong>ir cultural identityBox 3 ILO’s Convention on Indigenous and Tribal Peoples1989 (No. 169)ILO adopted <strong>the</strong> Indigenous and Tribal Peoples Convention(No. 169) to include <strong>the</strong> fundamental concept that<strong>the</strong> ways of life of indigenous and tribal peoples shouldand will survive. It also stressed that <strong>the</strong>se peoples and<strong>the</strong>ir traditional organisations must be closely involvedin <strong>the</strong> planning, design and implementation of developmentpolicies that affect <strong>the</strong>m. It sets <strong>the</strong> minimuminternational standards while opening <strong>the</strong> ground <strong>for</strong>higher standards in countries that can go fur<strong>the</strong>r.Convention No. 169 adopts a general attitude of respect<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> cultures and ways of life of indigenous andtribal peoples, placing emphasis on <strong>the</strong>ir right to acontinued existence and to development according to<strong>the</strong>ir own priorities.It is a comprehensive instrument covering a range ofissues pertaining to indigenous and tribal peoples,including land rights, recruitment and conditions ofemployment, access to natural resources, social securityand health, education and means of communication,vocational training, conditions of employment andcooperation and contacts across borders.Protection is still <strong>the</strong> main objective but it is based onrespect <strong>for</strong> indigenous and tribal people’s cultures, <strong>the</strong>irdistinct ways of life and <strong>the</strong>ir traditions and customs.It is also based on <strong>the</strong> belief that indigenous and tribalpeoples have <strong>the</strong> right to continue to exist with <strong>the</strong>irown identities and <strong>the</strong> right to determine <strong>the</strong>ir own wayand pace of development.145


through a variety of legal instruments and policies.They have ranged from outright exclusion toinclusion at very inferior conditions.The typical outcomes involved are dispossessionof <strong>the</strong>ir traditional lands, relocation withoutcompensation and basic support services; underinvestmentin education and health; ill-adaptededucational systems and materials — all of whichtranslate, among o<strong>the</strong>rs, into disadvantageousstatus in labour markets. ITPs expelled from <strong>the</strong>irancestral domains become seasonal, migrant,bonded or home-based labourers; <strong>the</strong>y are exposedto various <strong>for</strong>ms of exploitation. Discriminationin wage is common practice and <strong>the</strong>re ishigh incidence of <strong>for</strong>ced labour. Unemployment,especially youth unemployment, is higher amongITPs compared to <strong>the</strong> national average. 36The challenge lies in how to improve living andw<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions among ITPs so that <strong>the</strong>y cancontinue to exist as distinct peoples, if <strong>the</strong>y wishto do so. Specific ef<strong>for</strong>ts <strong>for</strong> legal empowermentof indigenous people have to be made. The ILO’sIndigenous and Tribal Peoples Convention (seeBox 3) provides guidance and strategies <strong>for</strong> legalempowerment with respect not only to labourrights and protection of employment, but also toland and property rights.Special ef<strong>for</strong>ts <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir legal empowerment aredemonstrated in an ‘ethnic audit’ of 14 PovertyReduction Strategy Papers (PRSPs) as well ascase studies of country processes in Bolivia,Cambodia, Cameroon, Guatemala and Nepal. Theresearch clearly showed that while indigenouspeoples are disproportionately represented among<strong>the</strong> poor, <strong>the</strong>ir needs and priorities are generallynot reflected in <strong>the</strong> strategies employed tocombat poverty.Legal empowerment of indigenous and tribalpeoples must address <strong>the</strong> structural causes of<strong>the</strong>ir disenfranchisement and social exclusionthrough:• Legal framew<strong>ork</strong>s that recognise individualand group rights.• Institutions and policies that respect and accommodatecultural diversity.• Organisation and mobilisation of indigenouspeople <strong>for</strong> participation and political change. 37ConclusionsThe vast majority of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor earn <strong>the</strong>irliving in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy where averageearnings are low, productivity is poor, w<strong>ork</strong>ingconditions are hazardous, and risks are high. Anyattempt to <strong>for</strong>mulate policies and approaches<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy must understand itscharacteristics, including <strong>the</strong> deep segmentationfound in it. This section provided a global pictureof <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, highlighting its size,segmentation, and <strong>the</strong> vulnerabilities of its particularsegments. Women dominate <strong>the</strong> most-disadvantagedcategories of in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>, 38 notablyindustrial outw<strong>ork</strong> and home-based production. Itis also in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy that child labourand bonded labour are most prevalent and mostdifficult to address. Indigenous and tribal peoplesare marginalized largely due to discrimination.Their cultural identity is suppressed and <strong>the</strong>y areexcluded from social services that should prepare<strong>the</strong>m <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> labour market; fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, when atw<strong>ork</strong>, <strong>the</strong>y face many <strong>for</strong>ms of discrimination.Despite early predictions of its eventual demise,<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy has not only grownworldwide but also emerged in new guises andunexpected places. Though understood to becounter-cyclical, different segments of <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy are seen to have differentcyclical patterns leading to different patternsof in<strong>for</strong>malisation across countries. In virtually146


all cases, <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy expands duringeconomic slumps or downturns, as expected.In some cases, <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy expandsduring periods of economic growth. Economicgrowth has been accompanied by an increase in<strong>the</strong> more dynamic micro-enterprise activities andsubcontracted w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> larger supply chains especiallythose linked to <strong>the</strong> global economy. Thus,<strong>the</strong> growing significance of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy— and its apparent endurance as a feature of <strong>the</strong>labour market — leads us to examine how labourrights can be applicable to <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ers found in itand what role legal empowerment of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malw<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce can play in breaking <strong>the</strong> vicious cycleof low productivity and poverty.4. Poverty and LabourRights: a new departurePoverty: A market failure and a publicpolicy failureThere is a broad consensus around <strong>the</strong> notionthat labour is not a commodity 39 and, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e,that labour markets are different from o<strong>the</strong>r markets.The labour market has a double function:it is a mechanism <strong>for</strong> both <strong>the</strong> creation of newresources and <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> distribution of income andprosperity. While enterprises should be subject tocompetition, which means that some will succeedand grow while o<strong>the</strong>rs will disappear, people orw<strong>ork</strong>ers have to be treated in a completely differentway. Public policies <strong>for</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ers and <strong>the</strong>irfamilies have to be focused on inclusion, on newopportunities <strong>for</strong> decent w<strong>ork</strong> and on shared prosperity(See Box 4 <strong>for</strong> an elaboration of <strong>the</strong> socialcase <strong>for</strong> labour regulation).147In addition to <strong>the</strong>ir intrinsic value <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ingpoor, labour rights standards are fundamental toupholding <strong>the</strong> human rights obligations of statesand o<strong>the</strong>r ‘organs of society’ as set out in <strong>the</strong>Universal Declaration of Human Rights and manyo<strong>the</strong>r international covenants, conventions, andtreaties, as well as set out in national legislationaround <strong>the</strong> globe. From <strong>the</strong> perspective of thisCommission, labour rights and regulations arealso fundamental to achieving legal employmentof <strong>the</strong> poor.Labour rights and labour standards have beenan issue <strong>for</strong> international promotion and regulation<strong>for</strong> almost a hundred years. All countries,including <strong>the</strong> poorest countries, in principleprovide <strong>the</strong>ir w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce with labour rights. Labourlaws and labour protection models are traditionallydesigned with <strong>the</strong> presumption of a <strong>for</strong>malemployer-employee relationship. This relation-


Box 4 Social case <strong>for</strong> labourregulationThe social case <strong>for</strong> labour market regulationsemanates, fi rst and <strong>for</strong>emost, from <strong>the</strong> principlethat labour is not a commodity. The distinction liesin <strong>the</strong> human aspect of labour. As such, its behaviouris affected by <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong> environment and by <strong>the</strong>incentives that are given. While machines operateaccording to technical specifications, labour has tobe motivated based on what <strong>the</strong>y care about. Theyare contracted to per<strong>for</strong>m a certain job and are paidwhen <strong>the</strong>y complete <strong>the</strong> job. The completion of <strong>the</strong>contract is not as straight<strong>for</strong>ward as it would be <strong>for</strong>non-human means of production as this requiresa complex range of in<strong>for</strong>mation on both sides andincentives to ensure compliance. 42ship has been <strong>the</strong> cornerstone around whichlabour law, collective bargaining agreements andsocial security systems are framed. Whatever itsprecise definition in different national contexts,<strong>the</strong> employment relationship has represented ‘auniversal notion which creates a link between aperson, called <strong>the</strong> employee (frequently referredto as <strong>the</strong> ‘w<strong>ork</strong>er’) with ano<strong>the</strong>r person, called<strong>the</strong> employer to whom she or he provides labouror services under certain conditions in return <strong>for</strong>remuneration.’ 40Despite <strong>the</strong> long-standing and wide-spreadcommitment to labour rights, a large majorityof w<strong>ork</strong>ers are excluded from labour rights andsocial protection. Thus, in<strong>for</strong>mality and povertyis not only a market failure, it is also a failure ofpublic policies. Several factors, in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m ofhistoric traditions, structural failures and conflictingpolitical interests, help explain <strong>the</strong> persistenceand growth of in<strong>for</strong>mality.• One explanation is <strong>the</strong> history of labour lawand regulation. Labour rights were historicallydesigned with <strong>the</strong> presumption of a <strong>for</strong>malemployment relationship thus excluding thosewithout a <strong>for</strong>mal employment relationship.• Ano<strong>the</strong>r explanation is a lack of confidencein laws and law en<strong>for</strong>cement. Some politicalregimes have fur<strong>the</strong>r undermined publicconfidence due to poor governance, causingmany enterprises to operate in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy.• A third explanation is a lack of public policyattention. Governments, employers, and w<strong>ork</strong>ers— <strong>the</strong> three social partners in <strong>the</strong> ILOstandard-setting systems — have focused on<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy and <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal organisedlabour <strong>for</strong>ce. The in<strong>for</strong>mal sector and in<strong>for</strong>malemployment have been studied and discussedsince <strong>the</strong> 1970s. A first discussion of <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal sector took place at <strong>the</strong> InternationalLabour Conference in 1991 and subsequently<strong>the</strong> International Labour Conference reachedpolicy conclusions regarding in<strong>for</strong>mal employmentin 2002. 41• Ano<strong>the</strong>r factor is weak and poorly-designeden<strong>for</strong>cement mechanisms. Countries that haveimproved <strong>the</strong> design and reach of <strong>the</strong>ir en<strong>for</strong>cementmechanisms to match <strong>the</strong> circumstancesof w<strong>ork</strong>ers and units in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy have been able to reduce in<strong>for</strong>mality.The relationship between in<strong>for</strong>mal employmentand poverty had not, until recently, received <strong>the</strong>attention <strong>the</strong>y deserve, much less reached <strong>the</strong> topof <strong>the</strong> development policy agenda. The interestto bring about re<strong>for</strong>m is quite new and <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>mstrategies, discussed by <strong>the</strong> ILO, World Bank, <strong>the</strong>international trade union movement and o<strong>the</strong>rs,and <strong>the</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>ts to develop feasible solutions bycountries with large in<strong>for</strong>mal economies, are stillin <strong>the</strong>ir early stages of development.148


A New Departure: Fundamental Principles andRights at W<strong>ork</strong>, <strong>the</strong> Decent W<strong>ork</strong> Agenda, andLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> W<strong>ork</strong>ing PoorThe recognition that productive employmentand decent w<strong>ork</strong> are key pathways to povertyreduction, and that in<strong>for</strong>mality represents both amarket failure and a public policy failure, haveled to a reassessment of development strategiesof <strong>the</strong> 20 th century, including <strong>the</strong> ILO labourstandard strategy. Over <strong>the</strong> past decade, tripartitediscussions on key related <strong>the</strong>mes at <strong>the</strong> annualinternational labour conferences have contributedto this review process, as have <strong>the</strong> activism,scholarship, and policy analysis of o<strong>the</strong>r stakeholders.What has emerged from this rethinkingis an international consensus around an agendaof fundamental principles and rights at w<strong>ork</strong>, alsoknown as core labour standards, decent w<strong>ork</strong> andlegal empowerment of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.The First Step: Fundamental Principles andRights at W<strong>ork</strong>: A first step in <strong>the</strong> developmentof new international strategies to fight povertyand social injustice through labour rights was <strong>the</strong>establishment by <strong>the</strong> International Labour Conferencein 1998 of a set of fundamental principlesand rights at w<strong>ork</strong>; <strong>the</strong>y include:• The right to freedom of association and collectivebargaining.• The elimination of all <strong>for</strong>ms of <strong>for</strong>ced or compulsorylabour.• The abolition of child labour.• The elimination of discrimination in employmentand occupation.Endorsed by <strong>the</strong> international community, <strong>the</strong>secore labour standards constitute a ‘minimumfloor’, necessary both <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> respect of fundamentalhuman rights and <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> effective functioningof labour markets. They are applicable toall w<strong>ork</strong>ers and economic units.The Second Step: The Decent W<strong>ork</strong> Agenda: Asecond step in <strong>the</strong> rethinking of traditional approacheswas <strong>the</strong> introduction at <strong>the</strong> InternationalLabour Conference in 1999 of <strong>the</strong> Decent W<strong>ork</strong>Agenda. Decent w<strong>ork</strong> is central to ef<strong>for</strong>ts to fightpoverty. It is captured in four strategic objectives:fundamental principles and rights at w<strong>ork</strong> andinternational labour standards; employment andincome opportunities; social protection and socialsecurity; and social dialogue and tripartism.These objectives hold <strong>for</strong> all w<strong>ork</strong>ers, women andmen, in both <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>mal economies;engaged in wage employment or w<strong>ork</strong>ing on <strong>the</strong>irown account; and w<strong>ork</strong>ing on <strong>the</strong> streets or infields, factories, small w<strong>ork</strong>shops, or offices; in<strong>the</strong>ir homes or in <strong>the</strong>ir neighbourhoods.Legal empowerment through labour rights is notonly a means <strong>for</strong> preventing a race to <strong>the</strong> bottom.Such legal empowerment can also be designedto create confidence, to facilitate change and tomaintain cohesion, as shown by many of <strong>the</strong> moreprosperous countries. Labour standards, collectiveagreements and social protection in <strong>the</strong>secountries contribute to defining minimum levelsof income and productivity. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, effectiveapplication of labour standards can contributeto giving a positive incentive <strong>for</strong> enterprisesin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy to increase <strong>the</strong>ir productivityand incomes and to <strong>for</strong>mal firms to extendlabour rights to all of <strong>the</strong>ir w<strong>ork</strong>ers: both core andperipheral, both direct and contracted hires, upand down <strong>the</strong>ir supply chains.Labour standards are not only about <strong>the</strong> protectionof w<strong>ork</strong>er rights. They also include promotionalmeasures, such as access to skillsupgrading, life long learning and productiveemployment.149


Box 5 ILO Conventions and Recommendations Pertinent to<strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal EconomyHuman capabilities andempowermentCore labour standards• Freedom of association andcollective bargaining(C87 and 98)• Equality (C 100 and 111)• Forced Labour (C 29 and 105)• Child Labour (C 138 and 182)(The Indigenous and Tribal PeoplesConvention, C 169, must also bementioned, in view of its provisionson educational measuresto eliminate prejudices and tocombat discrimination and fullrealisation of <strong>the</strong>ir rights.)Source: Anne Trebilcock 2004.Labour market policy framew<strong>ork</strong>s<strong>for</strong> bettergovernanceEmployment policy• Employment Policy(C 122 and R169)• Job Creation in SMEs(C 189)• Human Resource Development (C142 and R 195)Institutions of governance• LabourAdministration Convention(C 150)• Protection of Wages(C 95 and R 85)• Right to Organise and CollectiveBargaining (C 98 and 154)• Consultation (Industrial, National,and Tripartite (C 113 and 114)Protection of peopleSocial security instruments• Social Security (Minimum Standards)(C 102)• Indigenous and Tribal PeoplesConvention (C 169)• Maternity Protection (C 183)Safety and health instruments• Occupational Safety and Health(C 155 and R 164)• Guarding of Machinery (C 119) and W<strong>ork</strong>ingEnvironment (Air, Pollution, Noise and Vibration;C 148)• Safety and Health in Agriculture(C 184)• Rural W<strong>ork</strong>ers’ Organisation(C 141)• Various safety and health conventions inspecific sectors such as mining,construction, w<strong>ork</strong> involving asbestos andbenzene.The Third Step: Empower People in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>malEconomy: This step was taken in 2002 when <strong>the</strong>International Labour Conference discussed andadopted a resolution on Decent W<strong>ork</strong> and <strong>the</strong>In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy, representing a new departurein addressing <strong>the</strong> topic. The new conceptualframew<strong>ork</strong> depicts a continuum of productionand employment relations. It does away with <strong>the</strong>idea that <strong>the</strong>re are distinct <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>mal’sectors’ without direct links and instead stressesthat <strong>the</strong>re are ‘linkages, grey areas and interdependenciesbetween <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>mal activities.’The framew<strong>ork</strong> views <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>malenterprises and w<strong>ork</strong>ers as co-existing along acontinuum, with decent w<strong>ork</strong> deficits most seriousat <strong>the</strong> bottom, unprotected, unregulated, survivalistend, but also existing in some <strong>for</strong>mal jobsas well, and with increasingly decent conditionsmoving up towards <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal protected end. Byhighlighting <strong>the</strong> dynamic linkages between <strong>for</strong>maland in<strong>for</strong>mal activities, <strong>the</strong> policy issue can morerealistically be framed: <strong>the</strong> issue is not whe<strong>the</strong>rin<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers or in<strong>for</strong>mal units have direct tieswith <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy but whe<strong>the</strong>r those tiesare benign, exploitative or mutually beneficial.The policy concern must enhance <strong>the</strong> positivelinkages and ensure that <strong>the</strong>re is decent w<strong>ork</strong> allalong <strong>the</strong> continuum. 43150


The conclusions stressed <strong>the</strong> need to ‘eliminate<strong>the</strong> negative aspects of in<strong>for</strong>mality while at <strong>the</strong>same time ensuring that opportunities <strong>for</strong> livelihoodand entrepreneurship are not destroyed,and promoting <strong>the</strong> protection and incorporationof w<strong>ork</strong>ers and economic units in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy into <strong>the</strong> mainstream economy.’ With aspecial focus on countries struggling with abjectpoverty and with a rapidly growing labour <strong>for</strong>ce,<strong>the</strong> ILO resolution urged that measures taken‘should not restrict opportunities <strong>for</strong> those whohave no o<strong>the</strong>r means of livelihood. However, itshould not be a job at any price or under any circumstances.’A clear challenge <strong>for</strong> follow-up is todemonstrate how job quantity and quality can gotoge<strong>the</strong>r and how respect <strong>for</strong> basic labour rightsmight promote productivity growth. A relatedchallenge is to ensure that activities targeting<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy do not lead to <strong>the</strong> growthof poor quality employment, but ra<strong>the</strong>r to <strong>the</strong>upgrading of w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions. The conclusionsalso call <strong>for</strong> an upward transition, not a downwardpull along <strong>the</strong> continuum of decent w<strong>ork</strong>.Beyond <strong>the</strong> four core labour standards <strong>the</strong>re is arange of standards, including minimum wages,occupational safety and health, w<strong>ork</strong>ing hours,and maternity protection, which directly impactw<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions. These are determined nationallyand <strong>the</strong>ir application varies with <strong>the</strong> level ofdevelopment of <strong>the</strong> country and its capacity toen<strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong>se standards. 44 One convention of directrelevance to <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy is <strong>the</strong> ILOHome W<strong>ork</strong> Convention, adopted in 1996, whichw<strong>ork</strong>s to extend legal empowerment to homew<strong>ork</strong>ers (industrial outw<strong>ork</strong>ers who w<strong>ork</strong> from<strong>the</strong>ir homes), who are predominantly women.Compliance with <strong>the</strong>se standards can be viewedas progressive, where different segments of <strong>the</strong>labour market experience different degrees ofprotection. In reality, ‘<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal shades into <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal’ and people move between w<strong>ork</strong> opportunitieswith different degrees of protection. 45 Thegoal is to progressively achieve compliance with abroader range of standards throughout <strong>the</strong> wholeeconomy, leading to gradual <strong>for</strong>malisation of <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.It is instructive to highlight provisions in ILOConventions and Recommendations that maybe applicable to <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Theseinternational labour standards provide guidanceto national economic and social policies, includinghow such policies can be applied to decentw<strong>ork</strong> and <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. These Conventionsand Recommendations may be understoodunder <strong>the</strong> following broad objectives: (a) humancapabilities and empowerment, which relateto <strong>the</strong> core labour standards, (b) labour marketpolicy framew<strong>ork</strong>s <strong>for</strong> better governance, and(c) protection of people. 46 These standards <strong>for</strong>m<strong>the</strong> backbone of ILO’s Decent W<strong>ork</strong> agenda, andcover not only <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal sector but also, mostimportantly, <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. For it is in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy where decent w<strong>ork</strong> deficits arefound to be most challenging and disturbing.Towards a Global Social ContractAs noted above, <strong>the</strong> international communityhas endorsed three outcomes of <strong>the</strong> ILO’s internationallabour conferences over <strong>the</strong> past decade,which, taken toge<strong>the</strong>r, provide a strategicframew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> advancing <strong>the</strong> realisation of labourrights, reducing poverty, and expanding equityworldwide. The 1998 Declaration of FundamentalPrinciples and Rights at W<strong>ork</strong>, <strong>the</strong> 1999Decent W<strong>ork</strong> Agenda, and <strong>the</strong> 2002 Resolutionon <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy have made significantcontributions to what is now a widely-sharedcommitment to universally ensure a minimumfloor of fundamental labour rights; <strong>the</strong>y have alsorecognised that <strong>the</strong> final objective should be <strong>the</strong>151


provision of full, productive, freely-chosen andprotected employment in a democratic context offreedom of voice, organisation and social dialogue.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> extension of this commitmentto include <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce providesa comprehensive framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> inclusion of thoseamong <strong>the</strong> poorer segments of <strong>the</strong> populationwho are employed but register significant deficitsin regard to decent w<strong>ork</strong>.The 2005 World Summit of Heads of Statesstrongly supported <strong>the</strong> goal of fair globalizationand ‘resolved to make <strong>the</strong> goals of full andproductive employment and decent w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> all,including <strong>for</strong> women and young people, a centralobjective of our relevant national and internationalpolicies as well as our national developmentstrategies, including poverty reduction strategies,as part of our ef<strong>for</strong>ts to achieve <strong>the</strong> MillenniumDevelopment Goals.’ 47 This was followed by <strong>the</strong>UN Economic and Social Council (ECOSOC)2006 Ministerial Declaration, which emphasisedfull and productive employment and decentw<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> all as an end in itself and as a meansto achieve <strong>the</strong> Millennium Development Goals(MDGs), including poverty eradication. On thisoccasion, <strong>the</strong> multilateral system 48 was enjoinedto mainstream <strong>the</strong> goals of full and productiveemployment and decent w<strong>ork</strong> in all <strong>the</strong>ir policies,programmes and activities. 49The Decent W<strong>ork</strong> agenda has <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e been acceptedas a global goal and is no longer an ILOagenda alone. Decent w<strong>ork</strong> has been declaredas a goal not only <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal wage sector,but also <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. A decadelongprocess of rethinking international labourstandards has now led to an emerging globalsocial contract, a broad agenda <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m and <strong>for</strong>empowerment.The W<strong>ork</strong>ing Group on Labour Rights, in preparingthis chapter, saw an opportunity to move onestep fur<strong>the</strong>r and provide additional elements tothis emerging global social contract. We suggestadvancing simultaneously on labour rights,job creation and social protection, focusingparticularly on <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy.Labour rights <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers: what is anachievable minimum fl oor?All w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy should becovered at least by a ‘minimum floor’ as containedin <strong>the</strong> 1998 Declaration of Principles and Rightsat W<strong>ork</strong>. This Declaration established <strong>the</strong> applicationof core human rights to <strong>the</strong> arena of labour orw<strong>ork</strong>; included in its provisions are calls <strong>for</strong> no useof <strong>for</strong>ced or child labour, no discrimination, and<strong>the</strong> freedom of voice, organisation and bargaining.The Declaration also constitutes <strong>the</strong> foundations<strong>for</strong> implementing o<strong>the</strong>r labour rights and providingenabling conditions to exercise <strong>the</strong>m and, thus,achieving <strong>the</strong> objective of providing employmentopportunities while ensuring protection. 50 Thisminimum floor could include three additionallabour standards <strong>for</strong> determinants of w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions:hours of w<strong>ork</strong>, diseases and accidents atw<strong>ork</strong>, and minimum wage. 51What we are proposing here — an enlarged minimumfloor — has already gained internationalacceptance, notably during <strong>the</strong> last generation offree trade agreements of <strong>the</strong> United States andcountries of Asia and Latin America. The adoptionof such a minimum floor would ensure <strong>the</strong>rights to rest, to health coverage of w<strong>ork</strong>-relatedrisks, and to fair remuneration — all according tostandards established by national legislation. En<strong>for</strong>cementof such rights and provisions should berequired <strong>for</strong> all w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy,independently of <strong>the</strong> size or <strong>for</strong>m of <strong>the</strong> economicunit in which <strong>the</strong>y w<strong>ork</strong>. This would justify rein-152


<strong>for</strong>cement and, eventually, a redesign of labourinspection institutions.For in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers outside <strong>for</strong>mal enterprises,full compliance of labour rights as establishedby national legislation needs to be en<strong>for</strong>ced. Thisshould go beyond <strong>the</strong> minimum floor, requiringeventually re<strong>for</strong>ms to <strong>the</strong> labour legislation <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>facilitation of compliance. Advances in this directionwould lead to full achievement of <strong>the</strong> DecentW<strong>ork</strong> objectives.Un<strong>for</strong>tunately, not all employment relationshipsare explicit, where rights and obligationscan be clearly identified. Many w<strong>ork</strong>ers areemployed under diffuse employment relationswhere <strong>the</strong> relation is hidden or where <strong>the</strong>re areproblems in <strong>the</strong> application or interpretation of<strong>the</strong> law. There is need <strong>for</strong> additional policies todetermine if an employment relation exists and toclarify <strong>the</strong> responsibilities <strong>for</strong> compliance amongthose enterprises involving multi-parties. 52 Thelatter kinds of arrangements are continuing toexpand and are serving to decentralise <strong>the</strong> laboursystem in ef<strong>for</strong>ts, apparently, to reduce labourcosts. In <strong>the</strong> process, however, <strong>the</strong>y are often bypassinglabour regulations and collective bargainingagreements and eroding <strong>the</strong> power of unions.Interpretation of existing laws as well as newlegislation will be needed to regulate <strong>the</strong>se disguisedemployment arrangements, and to determinewhe<strong>the</strong>r an employment relationship existsand who is primarily responsible <strong>for</strong> obligationsto w<strong>ork</strong>ers. This essential first step in movingtowards compliance should be followed by appropriatelyadapting labour laws and <strong>the</strong> labourinspection system. 53The situation of w<strong>ork</strong>ers in in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprisesposes additional challenges, since <strong>the</strong> capacity ofmany in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises to absorb <strong>the</strong> cost ofcompliance is restricted by low productivity andincome. 54 As employment opportunities could bedestroyed in such cases, a strategy is needed <strong>for</strong>increasing compliance and promoting progressiveen<strong>for</strong>cement without legally adopting a dualsystem. An expanded minimum floor should, however,be en<strong>for</strong>ced even in <strong>the</strong>se enterprises, sincecost concern cannot be accepted as an argument<strong>for</strong> non-compliance given <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong> rightsinvolved and <strong>the</strong> fact that compliance does notnecessarily involve significant costs.Most standards require abstinence fromdiscriminatory or unlawful behaviour ra<strong>the</strong>rthan financial expenditure. A strategy could,however, recognise constraints where <strong>the</strong>y exist inaddition to <strong>the</strong> obligation to comply with a minimumfloor; basically, it should commit to gradualconvergence to full compliance and to verificationof progress towards this goal. This also requiresadapting <strong>the</strong> labour inspection procedures andpractices to move from sanctions to training in<strong>the</strong> early stages and to progressive compliance,as recommended by <strong>the</strong> ILO in a recent paper. 55A broad category that deserves special treatmentis that of home w<strong>ork</strong> (production or service w<strong>ork</strong>in a w<strong>ork</strong>er’s home) and domestic w<strong>ork</strong> (housecleaning, cooking <strong>for</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs). Included in thiscategory are significant numbers of w<strong>ork</strong>ers. W<strong>ork</strong>might involve producing <strong>for</strong> intermediaries insubcontracting arrangements as well as selling orproducing directly <strong>for</strong> employers. There is also aconcentration of women and use of family w<strong>ork</strong>that may involve children in <strong>the</strong>se activities.National labour laws do not usually cover domesticw<strong>ork</strong>ers; <strong>the</strong>y have no rights and little capacityto organise. Most are poor and experiencesignificant deficits of decent w<strong>ork</strong>. Employmentrelations, where <strong>the</strong>y exist, justify <strong>the</strong> applicationof rules covering o<strong>the</strong>r w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy. The convention (177) and a recommendation(184) adopted by <strong>the</strong> International153


Labour Conference in 1996, in recognition andsupport of home w<strong>ork</strong>ers, calls <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir equaltreatment with o<strong>the</strong>r w<strong>ork</strong>ers: in particular, itcalls <strong>for</strong> freedom of association in organisationsof <strong>the</strong>ir own choosing and protection againstdiscrimination, minimum age <strong>for</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>, remunerationand protection in safety and health at w<strong>ork</strong>,social security and maternity. This minimum floor<strong>for</strong> home w<strong>ork</strong>ers, mandated in <strong>the</strong> 1996 Conventionand Recommendation, coincides with whatis proposed above <strong>for</strong> all w<strong>ork</strong>ers of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy, with <strong>the</strong> addition of social protectionand maternity.Business and labour rights at w<strong>ork</strong>There are, in addition, a proportion of independenthome w<strong>ork</strong>ers that per<strong>for</strong>m a double role ofentrepreneur and w<strong>ork</strong>er and involve o<strong>the</strong>r familymembers in <strong>the</strong> production process. Independentw<strong>ork</strong>ers are also found beyond those who w<strong>ork</strong> athome and constitute around half of employmentin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Their identity is unclear,since <strong>the</strong>y are both employers and w<strong>ork</strong>ers, and<strong>the</strong>ir ways of organising should be open to <strong>the</strong>irpreferences. Their voice and <strong>the</strong>ir claims areusually directed against local governments and<strong>the</strong>ir behaviour in a highly competitive environmentis to operate in isolation to o<strong>the</strong>r producersor w<strong>ork</strong>ers in similar situations. In spite of <strong>the</strong>secharacteristics, <strong>the</strong> minimum floor is relevant andcould enable <strong>the</strong>se independents to organise,empowering <strong>the</strong>m to exercise both <strong>the</strong>ir labourand business rights. On <strong>the</strong> latter, improvementsin <strong>the</strong> regulatory environment and in processingwill result in increasing <strong>the</strong> opportunities to developbusinesses and in diminishing <strong>the</strong> barriersto grow. This should result in higher productivityand incomes.The International Labour Conference, in its 2007discussion on Sustainable Enterprises, 56 arguesthat ‘emphasis needs to be placed on <strong>the</strong> transitionof in<strong>for</strong>mal economy operators to <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>maleconomy and ensuring that laws and regulationscover all enterprises and w<strong>ork</strong>ers.’ The ILO Resolutionon <strong>the</strong> Promotion of Sustainable Enterprises,endorsed by employer, w<strong>ork</strong>er and governmentrepresentatives, argues that ‘poorly designedand unnecessary bureaucratic burdens on businesseslimit enterprise start-ups and <strong>the</strong> ongoingoperations of existing companies, and leadto in<strong>for</strong>mality, corruption and efficiency costs.’Well-designed transparent, accountable and wellcommunicatedregulations, including those thatuphold labour and environmental standards, aregood <strong>for</strong> markets and society. They facilitate <strong>for</strong>malisationand boost systemic competitiveness.Regulatory re<strong>for</strong>m and <strong>the</strong> removal of businesscontracts should not undermine such standards.Social protection <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ersThe extension of social protection — health andpensions, as well as maternity — to in<strong>for</strong>malw<strong>ork</strong>ers requires a strategy that considers differentoptions, from expanding coverage of existingsystems to <strong>the</strong> development of new mechanismsby <strong>the</strong> excluded, through pooling, of resources orinsurances. Alternatives should be considered,while examples of different schemes <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> provisionof protection need to be evaluated. Indiarecently introduced a bill to regulate employmentand service conditions of unorganised w<strong>ork</strong>ersand to provide <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir safety, social security,health and welfare and introduced a WelfareFund financed by government and registeredemployers with this purpose. 57 In <strong>the</strong> Philippines,<strong>the</strong> Statutory Social Security system and<strong>the</strong> health insurance plans have increased <strong>the</strong>ircoverage through voluntary schemes open to selfemployedw<strong>ork</strong>ers. 58From a systemic perspective, <strong>the</strong>se rights should154


e granted to people as citizens ra<strong>the</strong>r than asw<strong>ork</strong>ers, and <strong>the</strong>y should be awarded on <strong>the</strong>principle of universality. This has already been reflectedin Latin America, where some ‘traditionalmodels’ have been redesigned, by <strong>the</strong> additionof a publicly-financed ‘solidarity pillar’ to privatecontribution pension systems. In its recently publishedreport on in<strong>for</strong>mality in Latin America, 59<strong>the</strong> World Bank fully supports this change <strong>for</strong>both health and pension coverage. In <strong>the</strong> caseof health care, shocks that go uncovered imposesignificant costs to society. There<strong>for</strong>e, <strong>the</strong>re isa case <strong>for</strong> providing minimum essential healthcoverage, de-linked from <strong>the</strong> labour contract andfinanced through general taxation. Similarly, in<strong>the</strong> case of insufficient incomes in old age, <strong>the</strong>reare social costs involved that justify minimumincome support not linked to <strong>the</strong> labour contract.Chile, which pioneered <strong>the</strong> privatisation of <strong>the</strong>pension and health systems, is taking <strong>the</strong> lead inintroducing a non-contributory pillar that guaranteesa solidarity pension to all citizens above 65years old who receive a pension of 50 percent of<strong>the</strong> minimum wage. It will be universally granted,but efficiency is ensured by gradually reducing<strong>the</strong> subsidy <strong>for</strong> those who receive o<strong>the</strong>r pensions,thus reducing <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> public fundsand providing incentives to contribute to <strong>the</strong>system. In fact, <strong>the</strong> resulting model establishesa mid-way <strong>for</strong> non-contributory pensions, since itis universal <strong>for</strong> all citizens, but it recovers partly<strong>the</strong> fiscal contribution from high-income pensioners.Bolivia is <strong>the</strong> only country in Latin Americathat has introduced a universal non-contributorypension (BONOSOL) and Brazil has a similarsystem <strong>for</strong> rural w<strong>ork</strong>ers (FUNRUR<strong>AL</strong>). 60 Healthis covered to a larger extent than pensions andreaches universality by a combination of differentsystems: a social insurance system in CostaRica that covers contributors and non-contributors;a public-funded system in Cuba, and a mixof public institutions, social security and privateinsurances in Uruguay, Brazil and Chile, amongo<strong>the</strong>rs. Chile has streng<strong>the</strong>ned access to publichealth <strong>for</strong> all citizens by introducing an attentionguarantee of 56 basic pathologies (AUGE) inaddition to <strong>the</strong> existing national health insurance(FONASA).De-linking health and pension coverage from<strong>the</strong> labour market would create opportunitiesto increase employment and improve businesses,while guaranteeing security. It will helpdecrease <strong>the</strong> existing protection deficits but it willrequire sound fiscal policies and, particularly, <strong>the</strong>adequate funding of decent health and pensionscoverage. A similar approach should be used in<strong>the</strong> case of child care and maternity given <strong>the</strong>potential effect, respectively, on <strong>the</strong> early developmentof cognitive abilities in children and <strong>the</strong>participation of women, particularly those frompoor households, in <strong>the</strong> labour market.The Role and Limitations of Voluntary Codes ofConductMultinational corporations and non-governmentorganisations have also taken <strong>for</strong>ward <strong>the</strong> corelabour standards and <strong>the</strong> decent w<strong>ork</strong> agenda byestablishing voluntary codes of conduct, involvingin some cases subcontractors and outw<strong>ork</strong>ers.Codes of conduct constitute a strategy <strong>for</strong>motivating improvements in <strong>the</strong> per<strong>for</strong>manceof multinational corporations. Among <strong>the</strong> manyimportant initiatives are <strong>the</strong> Fair Labour Association,SA8000, <strong>the</strong> Clean Clo<strong>the</strong>s CampaignFoundation and <strong>the</strong> Ethical Trading Initiative.While <strong>the</strong> codes advanced through <strong>the</strong>se programmesvary, most of <strong>the</strong>m tend to be based onILO’s core standards, particularly <strong>the</strong> prohibitionof <strong>for</strong>ced labour, child labour, and discriminationin <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>place. These organisations take155


different paths to en<strong>for</strong>cement, with some takinga centralised approach in overseeing and controllingpayments <strong>for</strong> monitoring, while o<strong>the</strong>rs followa ‘consulting firm approach’ which allows companiesto choose and pay <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir own monitors.There is a need to move towards unified codes in<strong>the</strong> interest of promoting good governance in <strong>the</strong>business sector.Labour Rights, Social Protection, EmploymentCreation: trade-offs or complementarities?The emerging global social contract shouldinclude <strong>the</strong> promotion of more and better employmentopportunities and aim to reduce <strong>the</strong> existinggaps in protection, particularly concentratedin poorer population. It has to open opportunitiesas well as to provide protection. There are tradeoffsinvolved, but <strong>the</strong>re are also strong complementarities.The experience accumulated during<strong>the</strong> last decades could contribute to enhance <strong>the</strong>latter effects, without ignoring <strong>the</strong> lessons learntto diminish unnecessary costs introduced by illdesignedpolicies. Security provides incentives<strong>for</strong> learning and innovation and both are requirements<strong>for</strong> growth and employment creation. Thereis also need to facilitate adaptation of firms to <strong>the</strong>new competitive conditions, and this is particularlyrelevant in matters involving labour contractsand regulations.One of <strong>the</strong> lessons learnt is that <strong>the</strong> prescription<strong>for</strong> flexibility, through <strong>the</strong> introduction of temporaryor atypical labour contracts, has serious drawbacks, affecting more than <strong>the</strong> lives of w<strong>ork</strong>ersand <strong>the</strong>ir families. The rigidity of <strong>the</strong> permanentcontract and, particularly, <strong>the</strong> costs involved interminating this type of contract, could constitutea barrier in times of adjustment. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rhand, such contracts also provide a simple way ofprotection in countries where o<strong>the</strong>r mechanisms,like unemployment insurance, do not exist or arevery limited. The erosion of <strong>the</strong> permanent contractcan be changed by going back to a modifiedversion; <strong>for</strong> example, by introducing longer trialperiods, reducing or increasing <strong>the</strong> severancepayments in case of termination of employment,etc. The availability of temporary and fixed-termcontracts will still be needed, particularly to openwider opportunities <strong>for</strong> those more affected byunemployment and <strong>for</strong> those who wish to reconcileeducation or house-family care responsibilities.At <strong>the</strong> same time, temporary or fixed-termjobs should not replace permanent jobs and <strong>the</strong>limits of <strong>the</strong>ir use should be established throughconsultation and dialogue.The legal recognition of hidden employmentrelations or those without contracts will provideidentity to <strong>the</strong> affected w<strong>ork</strong>ers and constituteenabling conditions <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>m to exercise <strong>the</strong>irlabour rights, particularly labour and socialprotection. At <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>malisation ofemployment relations, even if gradually achieved,opens opportunities and provides incentives <strong>for</strong>improving business management. A culturalchange in <strong>the</strong> management of micro-enterprisesand, particularly, of family businesses is induced,since compliance with labour obligations requires<strong>the</strong> introduction of accountancy and cost benefitsanalysis to ensure viability of <strong>the</strong> enterprise. Theright of association is also conducive to developingalliances between producers, thus rein<strong>for</strong>cing<strong>the</strong>ir voice and <strong>the</strong>ir ability to negotiate with localauthorities; it is also enabling <strong>for</strong> potential pricereduction of <strong>the</strong>ir inputs and <strong>for</strong> easier accessto concentrated markets. This also representsa major cultural change since it means shiftingfrom individualistic to collective behaviour. Therehas been international tripartite consensus on <strong>the</strong>need to combat disguised employment relationships.National policy could serve to ensure effectiveprotection to w<strong>ork</strong>ers especially affected by156


uncertainty as to <strong>the</strong> existence of an employmentrelationship (w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, <strong>for</strong>example). 61ConclusionsThis review of development strategies and ofinternational labour standard setting showsthat <strong>the</strong>re is a growing political understandingof <strong>the</strong> fundamental importance of employmentand w<strong>ork</strong> conditions <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> fight against poverty.It also shows that <strong>the</strong>re is a new departure in<strong>the</strong> international community regarding labourrights and that w<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economynow is addressed. The three elements of this newdeparture — Fundamental Principles and Rightsat W<strong>ork</strong>, <strong>the</strong> Decent W<strong>ork</strong> Agenda and <strong>the</strong> rightsin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy — are now supported bya broad coalition of governments, internationalorganisations, trade unions and employers andnon-governmental organisations.5. The economics ofin<strong>for</strong>mality and <strong>the</strong> debateon Labour RegulationsThere is now a broad recognition of a decent w<strong>ork</strong>deficit in <strong>the</strong> global labour market - from <strong>the</strong> absenceof social protection to <strong>the</strong> absence of basicrights at w<strong>ork</strong>. A key economic indicator of thatdeficit, as explained by <strong>the</strong> ILO World Employmentreport of 2004/2005, is whe<strong>the</strong>r men andwomen can earn enough from <strong>the</strong>ir w<strong>ork</strong> to lift<strong>the</strong>mselves and <strong>the</strong>ir families out of poverty. For<strong>the</strong> estimated 500 million w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor who livein households with daily incomes of less thanUS$1 per capita, <strong>the</strong> answer is ‘no’. In <strong>the</strong>ir case,it is not <strong>the</strong> absence of economic activity that is<strong>the</strong> source of <strong>the</strong>ir poverty, but <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong>ireconomic activities. The link between w<strong>ork</strong> of lowquality or productivity and poverty is starkly clear:if people were able to earn more from <strong>the</strong>ir w<strong>ork</strong>,<strong>the</strong>n poverty would decline. Thus, it is not justany w<strong>ork</strong> per se which can raise individuals out ofpoverty; but ra<strong>the</strong>r productive and decent w<strong>ork</strong>.Taking this view as point of departure, <strong>the</strong> purposeof this section is to provide a brief overviewof <strong>the</strong> role of labour regulations in economic per<strong>for</strong>mance.We examine, firstly, some broad crosscountryevidence about <strong>the</strong> impact of labourregulations on growth and employment, makingreferences to a number of individual countrystudies. We <strong>the</strong>n proceed to what we would argueis an important addendum to reinterpretingprior assumptions regarding <strong>the</strong> nature, role andimpact of labour market regulations <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ingpoor of <strong>the</strong> world. Our recommendations arepresented at <strong>the</strong> end of this section.157


Table 1 Mean Measures of Regulation, by Income LevelArea of RegulationLowIncome LMI UMIHI - nonOECDHI -OECDTotalRigidity of Hiring 44.28 33.68 29.91 27.00 20.60 34.33Rigidity of Hours 47.60 39.64 40.57 45.22 32.00 42.40Rigidity of Firing 40.00 33.04 33.43 27.39 14.00 33.26Aggreg. Employment Index 43.96 35.45 34.64 33.20 22.20 36.66Hiring Costs 12.40 16.01 17.31 21.43 10.17 15.62Firing Costs 65.32 50.91 44.63 31.32 54.64 51.34Source: Doing Business, 2006 and authors’ own calculations1. ‘LMI’ refers to Lower Middle Income countries; UMI to Upper Middle Income countries and HI to High Income economies. These are standard classificationsdrawn from <strong>the</strong> World Bank’s World Development Report (2005).2. All indices are normalised to 100, with <strong>the</strong> italicised, composite indices <strong>the</strong> arithmetic mean of <strong>the</strong> preceding sub-indices.The economic impact of LabourRegulation: an overview of key resultsThis section provides an overview of some of<strong>the</strong> key measures and results from <strong>the</strong> InvestmentClimate Assessment (ICA) surveys and <strong>the</strong>Doing Business Survey (DBS) both run under<strong>the</strong> auspices of <strong>the</strong> World Bank with a focus onsummary measures of labour market regulationand w<strong>ork</strong>er protection. 62 In turn, we raise somecaution about <strong>the</strong> interpretative value and policyrelevance of <strong>the</strong>se results.Most studies of labour regulation are basedon <strong>the</strong> assumption that such regulationsare, in one <strong>for</strong>m or ano<strong>the</strong>r, obstacles to businessoperation, and hence, to productivity and prosperity.These studies rarely address <strong>the</strong> intrinsic valueof regulations, or <strong>the</strong> perceived need or politicaleconomic circumstances that gave rise to <strong>the</strong> regulationsin <strong>the</strong> first place. 63 A first question is whatrole labour regulations play relative to o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>msof regulation in hindering <strong>the</strong> growth of firms. Thisquestion was addressed recently in an ICA survey.The conclusion of this survey was that <strong>the</strong> topten most frequently reported obstacles to growingbusiness operation were: policy uncertainty, macroinstability, tax rates, corruption, cost and access tofinance, crime, regulation and tax administration,skills, court and legal systems, and electricity.Labour regulation came in at eleventh place,reported by 16 percent of <strong>the</strong> respondents. Morepointed evidence from <strong>the</strong> Business EnterpriseSurvey Unit of <strong>the</strong> World Bank, which includes<strong>the</strong> ICA surveys, suggests that firms around <strong>the</strong>world do not necessarily view labour regulationsas a dominant determinant of, nor obstacles to,growing <strong>the</strong>ir businesses. The evidence suggeststhat less than six percent of all firms, irrespectiveof size, view labour regulations as a ‘severe’or ‘major’ obstacle to business expansion. Thisfigure is between 2.5 and 5.5 percent <strong>for</strong> lowincome, lower middle-income and upper middleincomeeconomies. In <strong>the</strong> case of high-income(OECD) economies, <strong>the</strong> estimate is about 10.5percent (World Bank, 2007). No significantlydifferent estimates are derived by size of <strong>the</strong>enterprise. There<strong>for</strong>e, and notwithstanding <strong>the</strong>iroverall limited relevance to business growth, <strong>the</strong>perception of <strong>the</strong> relevance of labour regulationsto business growth increases with <strong>the</strong> level ofdevelopment. There<strong>for</strong>e, in contrast to <strong>the</strong> DBS158


surveys discussed below, <strong>the</strong> ICA surveys indicatethat labour regulations appear to be of even morelimited relevance to low-income countriesIn contrast to <strong>the</strong> ICA surveys, <strong>the</strong> DBS is focusedon a detailed assessment of <strong>the</strong> regulatoryenvironment in individual economies. It hasan extensive labour regulation module, whichis based very closely on <strong>the</strong> methodology of <strong>the</strong>Botero et al (2004) study. 64 In addition, <strong>the</strong> DBSis <strong>the</strong> most recent, and indeed, possibly <strong>the</strong> mostwidely used measure of labour regulation andw<strong>ork</strong>er protection within an international context.Hence, despite some reservations expressedregarding <strong>the</strong> DBS, it continues to be a centralin<strong>for</strong>mation base <strong>for</strong> policymakers and investorsalike. For this reason, our w<strong>ork</strong>ing group <strong>for</strong>Chapter 3 of this report has made review of <strong>the</strong>methodology of <strong>the</strong> DBS and <strong>the</strong> debate on <strong>the</strong>DBS <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>for</strong> policy recommendations.The table above presents a snapshot of <strong>the</strong>key measures available to <strong>the</strong> public user,from <strong>the</strong> dataset. We present <strong>the</strong> data by countryincome level. All measures are converted to anindex ranging between 0 and 100. Values closerto 100 indicate higher levels of rigidity or protection.The ‘difficulty-of-hiring’ index measuresrestrictions on part-time and temporary contracts,toge<strong>the</strong>r with <strong>the</strong> wages of trainees relative tow<strong>ork</strong>er value-added. The rigidity of hours measures<strong>the</strong> various restrictions around weekend, Sundaypublic holiday w<strong>ork</strong>, as well as limits on overtime,and so on. The ‘firing’ index examines specificredundancy clauses within <strong>the</strong> relevant legislationin detail. What <strong>the</strong> DBS refers to as hiring costs,are in effect social protection costs, measuring allsocial security and health costs associated withhiring a w<strong>ork</strong>er. Finally, <strong>the</strong> cost of firing, measures<strong>the</strong> costs of terminating <strong>the</strong> employment ofan individual in terms of legislated notice-periodrequirements, severance pay, and so on.From <strong>the</strong> aggregate cross-country data, <strong>the</strong>re isan interesting bifurcation in <strong>the</strong> regulation andprotection measures. Hence, <strong>the</strong> data indicatethat <strong>the</strong> highest measures <strong>for</strong> any area of regulationrelating to rigidity in hiring, firing and hoursof w<strong>ork</strong> are found in low income economies,with <strong>the</strong> lowest level of employment regulationamongst high income OECD economies. In addition,<strong>the</strong> data show that firing costs are also <strong>the</strong>highest amongst low income countries, althoughnotably hiring costs are <strong>the</strong> highest in non-OECDhigh income economies.The Consequences of Labour Market RegulationThere are two important questions on policy issuesthat are of relevance to <strong>the</strong> debate aroundlabour regulation and w<strong>ork</strong>er protection. Thefirst revolves around <strong>the</strong> consequences of labourregulation, in all its different manifestations, <strong>for</strong>economic growth: do we find evidence that labourmarket regulation hinders economic growth? Thesecond issue is related, but more concerned with<strong>the</strong> specific outcomes in <strong>the</strong> labour market, as aconsequence of this regulatory regime: does <strong>the</strong>evidence suggest <strong>for</strong> example, that higher levelsof labour regulation are correlated with higherrates of youth unemployment, larger in<strong>for</strong>malemployment and so on?A number of studies suggest that regulationin general, and labour regulation in particular,is negatively and significantly associated withgrowth in per capita GDP (Loayza et al, 2006;Forteza and Rama, 2001; Heckman and Pagés,2003). On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, Botero et al (2004)find that ‘There is no evidence that employmentlaws or collective relations laws vary with <strong>the</strong>level of economic development.’ 65 Loayza et alshow that <strong>the</strong> effect of regulation is graduallymitigated as governance — and thus regulatoryquality — improves.159


However, a more detailed examination of <strong>the</strong>above literature suggests that <strong>the</strong> crosscountrygrowth regressions often reflect ei<strong>the</strong>r on<strong>the</strong> specific components of <strong>the</strong> labour regulatoryregime that may be hindering growth, or indeedrepresent <strong>the</strong> entire gamut of labour legislationas one index. Both <strong>the</strong>se approaches and subsequentresults suggest that <strong>the</strong>re is a heterogeneityin <strong>the</strong> labour regulatory regime that needs tobe grasped, and fur<strong>the</strong>rmore that this heterogeneitycan have a differential impact on economicgrowth. For example, Forteza and Rama (2001)find in one of <strong>the</strong>ir set of results, that over <strong>the</strong>period 1970-86, <strong>the</strong> number of ILO Conventionsratified is insignificantly related to GDP growth,but that <strong>the</strong> minimum wage indicator is negativeand significant. Loayza et al (2006), in turn, finda significant and negative relationship betweeneconomic growth and <strong>the</strong> labour regulation index,but this index is represented as an aggregatemeasure, and is not expanded into <strong>the</strong> componentsnoted in Table 1.The evidence on <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> labour regulatoryregime on specific labour market indicators,in addition, suggests similar outcomes andconsequent concerns. Hence higher levels oflabour regulation appear to be significantly associatedwith a larger in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, higherin<strong>for</strong>mal employment, reduced male participationrates and higher unemployment rates particularlyamongst <strong>the</strong> youth (Botero et al. 2004;Loayza et al. 2006; Lazear 1990). However,once again, <strong>the</strong>se results are ei<strong>the</strong>r too aggregatedin <strong>the</strong>ir measure of labour regulation, orindeed, do reflect on <strong>the</strong> heterogeneous impact oflabour regulation on <strong>the</strong>se labour market indicators.Specifically, <strong>the</strong>n, it is not clear whe<strong>the</strong>rall components of labour regulation and w<strong>ork</strong>erprotection encourage growth of in<strong>for</strong>mal employment,or some components do so more thano<strong>the</strong>rs. This would seem to be a critical avenueof enquiry — in order to better assist <strong>the</strong> currentpolicy debate. In addition, where such specificityis isolated, as in <strong>the</strong> Botero et al (2004) study,one finds that certain components of <strong>the</strong> labourregime are more important than o<strong>the</strong>rs in shapinglabour market outcomes. Hence, protective collectiverelations laws, but no o<strong>the</strong>r components of<strong>the</strong> labour regulatory architecture, are shown tobe associated with a larger in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.Across-country growth regression analysis(using <strong>the</strong> ordinary least squares approach)serves to illustrate <strong>the</strong> problem of aggregatingacross indices to arrive at firm conclusions. Ifsuch a regression is run on <strong>the</strong> DBS 2006 results,and simply includes most of <strong>the</strong> individualregulation indices — ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> compositemeasures often utilised - <strong>the</strong> regulatory effectsincluding those <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> labour market aremuted. Hence, of <strong>the</strong> individual labour regulatorymeasures in this admittedly very simplisticspecification, two of <strong>the</strong> five (hiring costs andhours rigidity) are significant at <strong>the</strong> five percentlevel. Notably however, <strong>the</strong> signs on both <strong>the</strong>secoefficients are positive, indicating, <strong>for</strong> example,that higher hiring costs (and hours of rigidity) areassociated with higher GNI per capita economies.This does not mean, however, that regulation ingeneral and labour regulation in particular, arenot important in <strong>the</strong> growth debate. Instead, itdoes suggest some caution in our interpretationof <strong>the</strong> published results and, more importantly,<strong>the</strong>ir translation into country-level policy interventionswithout due consideration both to <strong>the</strong>heterogeneity in <strong>the</strong> regulatory environment, andto country-specific conditions.Two additional caveats to <strong>the</strong> debate relating to<strong>the</strong> impact of labour regulation are worth noting.Firstly, that <strong>the</strong> absolute impact of labour regulationmay, even when using composite measures,160


e lower than that created by o<strong>the</strong>r regulatoryindices. Hence, Loayza et al (2006) note thatwhile GDP growth declines by 0.42 percentagepoints <strong>for</strong> every one standard deviation increasein an economy’s (composite) labour regulation index,this estimate <strong>for</strong> product market regulationsis over four times as large, at 1.86 percentagepoints. The fact is that <strong>the</strong> negative correlationof labour regulation with average income is notstatistically significant.Secondly, (and again drawing on Loayza et al[2006]), good governance and <strong>the</strong> quality of regulations,noted below, do make a difference. Hence,specifications controlling <strong>for</strong> quality of regulation,do appear to erode some of <strong>the</strong> negative impact oflabour and product market regulations on growth.For labour market regulations, <strong>the</strong> threshold ofgovernance quality required is relatively low andcomparable to Ireland and Portugal. For productmarket regulations, <strong>the</strong> threshold is quite high andcomparable to <strong>the</strong> quality of governance in Switzerland,United States and England. Hence, <strong>the</strong>notion that labour regulations can and do interactwith <strong>the</strong> quality of <strong>the</strong>ir application in explaininggrowth outcomes and does so in a non-linear manner,is a nuance that should not be lost.Thirdly, one of <strong>the</strong> indicators in <strong>the</strong> DBS, <strong>the</strong> ‘employingw<strong>ork</strong>ers indicator’ (EWI), is now subjectto a debate between <strong>the</strong> ILO and <strong>the</strong> World Bank.While <strong>the</strong> Bank recently has revised its policy torequire that its contractors respect core labourstandards, <strong>the</strong> ILO claims that recommendationsbased on EWI are contrary to that policy. In a reviewof <strong>the</strong> EWI <strong>the</strong> ILO states that <strong>the</strong> index doesnot take into account <strong>the</strong> reasons of labour legislation.The ILO in fact argues that ‘<strong>the</strong> narrow andlimited methodological foundations <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> EWI areinsufficient and possibly damaging as a guide topolicy <strong>for</strong>mulation.’ 66On <strong>the</strong> general aspect of regulation and in<strong>for</strong>malitysome studies focus on <strong>the</strong> voluntary aspectsof in<strong>for</strong>mality. 67 By avoiding taxes and regulatoryobligations, it is believed that in<strong>for</strong>mal companiesgain a substantial cost advantage that allows<strong>the</strong>m to stay in business despite <strong>the</strong>ir small scaleand low productivity. More productive, <strong>for</strong>malcompanies are prevented from gaining marketshare. The result is slower economic growth andjob creation. 68The International Organisation of Employers(IOE) 69 describes <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy as‘largely negative,’ trapping individuals and enterprisesin a spiral of low productivity and poverty.For governments it entails <strong>the</strong> loss of revenue,‘and <strong>for</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ers it can mean inferior w<strong>ork</strong>ingconditions, job insecurity, lack of access to statebenefits and social security.’The Impact of Labour Market Regulation: CountryStudiesA recent OECD 70 study found that making firingmore expensive <strong>for</strong> older w<strong>ork</strong>ers will protect<strong>the</strong>m against dismissal while severance paymentsallow w<strong>ork</strong>ers to smooth consumption duringunemployment periods. They also increase <strong>the</strong>incentive <strong>for</strong> longer-lasting employment relationships,which may increase w<strong>ork</strong>er satisfactionand productivity. At <strong>the</strong> aggregate level, morestable employment-relations foster technologicalprogress and skill upgrading 71 and, in an argumentfrequently used in Latin America, w<strong>ork</strong>erprotection, <strong>the</strong>y correct potential power asymmetriesbetween employees and firms. 72Yet, various studies have shown that firing costscan lead to greater in<strong>for</strong>mality. They increase costsby <strong>for</strong>cing firms to keep non-productive w<strong>ork</strong>ersin <strong>the</strong> firm, or to remain overstaffed <strong>for</strong> significantperiods of time. Thus it makes it more difficult<strong>for</strong> firms to fire, but also to hire. In developed161


countries this translates into unemployment, andin Latin America (which, however, is often overregulated),it translates into lower <strong>for</strong>mal labourdemand and larger in<strong>for</strong>mality. For instance:• A recent study that explicitly models <strong>the</strong>impact of firing costs over labour demand inPeru shows that an increase in expected severancepayments has a negative correlation with<strong>for</strong>mal labour demand. 73• Kugler et al. 74 found that in Spain a reductionin payroll taxes and firing costs increased <strong>the</strong>demand <strong>for</strong> permanent w<strong>ork</strong>ers.• Acemoglu and Angrist, in an interesting studyabout <strong>the</strong> effects of <strong>the</strong> American DisabilityAct, found that outlawing <strong>the</strong> firing of disabledw<strong>ork</strong>ers actually reduced labour demand <strong>for</strong>disabled w<strong>ork</strong>ers, precisely <strong>the</strong> opposite effectthat <strong>the</strong> law intended. 75The recent w<strong>ork</strong> on <strong>the</strong> Indian labour regulatoryregime (Besley and Burgess, 2004; Ahsan andPagés 2007) suggests that <strong>the</strong> clauses linked tofirm size within <strong>the</strong> industrial disputes regulatoryarchitecture may have had a deleterious impacton <strong>the</strong> growth of <strong>the</strong> economy’s manufacturingindustry (Ahmed and Devarajan, 2007). However,once again, <strong>the</strong>se conclusions are incomplete:Firstly, <strong>the</strong> Indian experience indicates that while<strong>the</strong> regulations are a part of <strong>the</strong> problem, in somecases <strong>the</strong> operational and logistical inefficienciesas well complexities associated with settlingdisputes (Ahmed and Devarajan, 2007) are significantin explaining <strong>the</strong> lack of expansion withinmanufacturing. Secondly, while amending partsof <strong>the</strong> regulatory framew<strong>ork</strong> is necessary it is alsotrue that active labour market programmes andpolicies, such as those recommended by <strong>the</strong> ILO<strong>for</strong> India, must be part of any attempt at encouragingsecure employment creation and reducingpoverty levels.Towards a More NuancedUnderstanding of Labour RegulationsThe above has suggested that, on <strong>the</strong> basis of<strong>the</strong> assembled evidence, <strong>the</strong> labour regulatoryenvironment is important in <strong>the</strong> debate aroundoutput expansion and employment growth indomestic economies. This fact however, shouldnot translate into too blunt an interpretation,and consequent policy advice, on re<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>the</strong>labour legislative environment at <strong>the</strong> individualcountry level.Some caveats need to be introduced here if amore in<strong>for</strong>med debate around labour regulationand policy re<strong>for</strong>m in <strong>the</strong> developing world is toensue. They may help to ensure progress in dealingappropriately and intelligibly with <strong>the</strong> labourmarket in <strong>the</strong> event that policy re<strong>for</strong>m packagesare tabled at country level. Perhaps economists,who are often at <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>efront of such re<strong>for</strong>mprocesses, should understand <strong>the</strong> most importantof <strong>the</strong>se cautionary notes. The caveat is thatlabour regulation as a re<strong>for</strong>m issue, is not to beviewed as a binary variable. The choice withinany policy re<strong>for</strong>m package in most economiesis never between no labour regulation at all andcomplete, comprehensive legislation. Unduefocus by economists on extreme deregulationof <strong>the</strong> labour market often results in no re<strong>for</strong>mat all. The notion that a labour market, like anyproduct market, needs to be as deregulated as faras is <strong>the</strong>oretically possible, can result in contentiousand not very productive policy debates. In<strong>the</strong> conclusions of <strong>the</strong> study on Impact of Regulationand Growth and In<strong>for</strong>mality, Loayza et al.bring a similar message. They emphasise that<strong>the</strong>ir study ‘does not intend to assess <strong>the</strong> impactof regulation on social goals that could be beyond<strong>the</strong> strict sphere of economic growth — broadgoals such as social equity and peace, or narrowones as w<strong>ork</strong>er safety, environmental conserva-162


tion, and civil security, which typically motivatesspecific regulations. Thus, our conclusions on <strong>the</strong>role of regulation must necessarily be evaluatedin a more comprehensive context be<strong>for</strong>e drawingdefinitive social welfare implications.’One specific manifestation of this problematicparadigm lies in <strong>the</strong> area of union power.For economists, this is a standard sub-measure ofrigidity in <strong>the</strong> labour market. Within <strong>the</strong> Botero etal study (2004), <strong>for</strong> example, it is captured under<strong>the</strong> collective rights index. However, <strong>for</strong> many legalexperts <strong>the</strong> right to join a union and <strong>the</strong> freedomof association are viewed as universal rightsissues and not by any means as matters touchingon labour market regulation. Such experts wouldalso view positively <strong>the</strong> idea that <strong>the</strong> greater <strong>the</strong>number of unionised individuals in a society <strong>the</strong>stronger <strong>the</strong> indication of a thriving democraticsociety with enshrined individual rights andinterests. The notion that union membership issomehow coupled with labour market rigidity isana<strong>the</strong>ma to a significant proportion of <strong>the</strong> legalcommunity. Indeed, policy consistency is requiredwhen stressing <strong>the</strong> importance of democracyand good governance to economic growth on<strong>the</strong> one hand, while reflecting on rigidity inducedby high levels of union power on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r.Interpretation of RegulationsThe standard measures of regulation found in <strong>the</strong>DBS are, as noted above, numeric conversions ofcountry-level legislative provisions. The DBS doesnot proclaim to do any more than this. However,it is worth reiterating <strong>the</strong> importance of how suchlegislation is interpreted by both <strong>the</strong> courts of lawand <strong>the</strong> relevant institutions of authority (such as,<strong>for</strong> example, dispute resolution bodies). Legislativeprovisions are more often than not, subject tointerpretation by <strong>the</strong> relevant legal authority. Howjudges, <strong>for</strong> example, interpret <strong>the</strong> notion of ‘fairdismissal’ falls to a variety of different variablesincluding <strong>the</strong> subjective opinion of <strong>the</strong> judge; <strong>the</strong>merits of <strong>the</strong> particular case; <strong>the</strong> evolution of jurisprudenceon relevant issues raised in <strong>the</strong> case;<strong>the</strong> resources available to <strong>the</strong> parties and so on.The simultaneous impact of <strong>the</strong>se variables would<strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong>n lead to a specific interpretation of<strong>the</strong> law. The outcome, as a consequence of <strong>the</strong>sefactors, may be an over-regulation or indeedunder-regulation of specific labour market activitiessuch as reasons <strong>for</strong> dismissal; unfair labourpractices; probation rights and so on.Simply put, <strong>the</strong> interpretation of labour legislationby <strong>the</strong> vested authorities may in fact yield ameasure of regulation that is at odds with thoseproduced by surveys such as <strong>the</strong> DBS and ICAs.The reality, however, is that attempting to extend<strong>the</strong> DBS measure into <strong>the</strong> realm of court judgementsand <strong>the</strong>ir orientation is almost impossible.However, it is essential to note <strong>the</strong>m in any discussionthat measures labour regulation within acountry. Implicitly, legislative provisions representan incomplete and less than satisfying measureof labour regulation in an economy.There is ano<strong>the</strong>r layer to understanding <strong>the</strong> legislativeenvironment in relation to <strong>the</strong> labour market:In many countries, its labour law architectureflows from, and is intricately and deliberatelylinked to, both its international and complementarydomestic legal obligations. Hence, drasticpolicy interventions designed to deregulate aneconomy’s labour market, may require due recognitionof <strong>the</strong> ILO Conventions that a country hasalready ratified. In addition, rights of an individualenshrined in <strong>the</strong> country’s constitution serveas <strong>the</strong> bedrock from which specific labour lawprovisions are made. Tampering with <strong>the</strong> latter ina substantive manner may indeed be unconstitutional.The generic point, however, is that shouldderegulating a labour market involve significant,163


legislative changes, it will critically impact on <strong>the</strong>broader legal environment of most countries. Insum, <strong>the</strong> notion of deregulating a labour marketmay indeed have significant and possibly intractablelegal outcomes.The Institutional EnvironmentThe extent to which <strong>the</strong> institutional environmentrein<strong>for</strong>ces or hinders legislativeprovisions is often under-appreciated in debatesaround labour market regulation. In most economies,institutions govern and manage <strong>the</strong> labourmarket. These include employer and employeeorganisations; <strong>the</strong> courts of law including specialistcourts; institutions of dispute resolution;ministries of labour or employment; collectivebargaining institutions; tripartite institutions andso on. These institutions will be differentiallyresourced in human and physical terms; will yieldcontrasting per<strong>for</strong>mances according to pre-setobjectives; will have different governance structures,parameters of influence and ultimatelypower within <strong>the</strong> society and so on. Simply put,<strong>the</strong>se range of factors, all of which are time andcontext-dependent, can and will fundamentallyalter <strong>the</strong> manner in which labour regulatory provisionsimpact on <strong>the</strong> economy.Two examples would suffice: Firstly, a sectoralminimum wage regulation mandated by governmentwill have little impact on ei<strong>the</strong>r wages oremployment, if en<strong>for</strong>cement and oversight of thisregulation through <strong>the</strong> relevant institutions is ofa poor quality. In such a case, economic outcomescould potentially be relatively benign if <strong>the</strong>institutional oversight is weak and poor in quality.Secondly, in many developing countries, <strong>the</strong> courtsystem is poorly resourced and inefficient. Therule of law takes a long time to be implementedin economies with an inefficient judicial system.For labour law cases, this could mean that rigidityin <strong>the</strong> labour market is more about an inefficientjudiciary than any aspect of wages, union poweror indeed <strong>the</strong> labour legislation itself. Ultimatelyhowever, <strong>the</strong> almost obvious point is that institutionsmatter, and nowhere more so than within<strong>the</strong> labour regulatory environment.Institutions should also matter to economistswhen examining <strong>the</strong> issue of labour regulation.Apart from <strong>the</strong> binary variable issue noted above,or <strong>the</strong> idea that perfectly competitive output andfactor markets are <strong>the</strong> optimal outcomes, <strong>the</strong>importance of institutions is often overlooked in<strong>the</strong>se debates. In our view, institutions that areefficient and complement <strong>the</strong> interaction betweenindividuals are good <strong>for</strong> growth, and this fitswithin <strong>the</strong> classic understanding of an efficientlyfunctioning labour market. Especially high qualityinstitutions can help to ensure that this marketfunctions efficiently and competitively. It is notclear that malfunctioning or non-existent, institutionsare an appropriate and acceptable condition<strong>for</strong> an optimally functioning labour market.Heterogeneity in <strong>the</strong> Regulatory ArchitecturePerhaps one of <strong>the</strong> key elements of this debatearound labour regulation, growth and in<strong>for</strong>malityis to acknowledge <strong>the</strong> distinction between grades,types and levels of labour regulation. This is an allusionto <strong>the</strong> key, albeit obvious, point that <strong>the</strong>re isa distinction between <strong>the</strong> establishment and protectionof core labour standards on <strong>the</strong> one hand,and <strong>the</strong> more detailed specifications around <strong>the</strong>nature of hiring and firing clauses <strong>for</strong> example. Itis often around <strong>the</strong> latter that much useful debateis to be had. However, it is important that <strong>the</strong> protectionand promotion of labour standards remainsat <strong>the</strong> core of any in-country labour market policyprogramme. This is critical to ensuring that <strong>the</strong>labour rights agenda is complementary to a widerset of actions to improve both <strong>the</strong> quality of w<strong>ork</strong>164


and <strong>the</strong> quantity of employment opportunities in<strong>the</strong> developing world. The securing of core labourstandards we believe is at <strong>the</strong> core of promoting<strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor and indeed<strong>the</strong> kernel of a decent w<strong>ork</strong> agenda.Some recognition, however, needs to be given to<strong>the</strong> possibility that labour regulation beyond corelabour standards may, under certain conditions,exacerbate segmentation in <strong>the</strong> labour market.Aspects of labour regulation may rein<strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong>insider-outsider divide by promoting barriers tohiring and firing. While this can reduce turnover,it may also affect employment growth.• Thirdly, we are of <strong>the</strong> opinion that more attentionshould be given to critical factors such as<strong>the</strong> nature and quality of legal institutions and<strong>the</strong> interpretation of <strong>the</strong> law. Better governanceis strongly correlated with economicgrowth and prosperity.ConclusionsThis review of <strong>the</strong> economic impact of labourregulation has led us to draw <strong>the</strong> following policyconclusions:• First, a methodological conclusion: we suggestcaution in interpretation of <strong>the</strong> published results,particularly from cross-country studies,and more importantly, <strong>the</strong>ir translation intocountry-level policy interventions without dueconsideration both to <strong>the</strong> heterogeneity in <strong>the</strong>regulatory environment, and country-specificconditions. This is confirmed both by <strong>the</strong> findingsin <strong>the</strong> Investment Climate Assessment,presented in <strong>the</strong> beginning of this section, andof <strong>the</strong> conclusions in <strong>the</strong> cross country analysismade by Loayza et al.• Secondly, we suggest a shift of focus from <strong>the</strong>ideological question on regulation or deregulation,to <strong>the</strong> question how such regulation canbe used to promote decent w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ingpoor. Thus, <strong>the</strong> debate on labour regulationsshould focus on what is <strong>the</strong> right balancebetween security, supportive structures, andflexibility <strong>for</strong> firms in both <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal andin<strong>for</strong>mal economy.165


6. Principles and practicesof Labour Rights and LegalEmpowermentThe task of <strong>the</strong> Commission <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor is to identify how legal instrumentscan be used to empower <strong>the</strong> poor. In thischapter we addresses one of <strong>the</strong> key areas oflegal empowerment, namely how internationaland national systems of labour standards andlabour rights can become more inclusive andpromote more productive and decent w<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong>fight against poverty. There is - in this arena as ino<strong>the</strong>r arenas of legal empowerment - no quick fix<strong>for</strong> shifting from in<strong>for</strong>mal and low productive employmentto decent and productive employment.There is no single solution, which can be appliedin all countries. A strategy <strong>for</strong> empowerment hasto have common core principles but remain flexibleenough in design to fit many different economic,social and political conditions. It has tobe participatory, inclusive and gender sensitive.Some principles are basic <strong>for</strong> any re<strong>for</strong>m strategyin this field and <strong>the</strong>y are introduced in Section6.1. There are many lessons to learn from recentnational and local initiatives <strong>for</strong> empowerment,which will be presented in Section 6.2. Someconclusions are drawn in 6.3. On <strong>the</strong> basis of<strong>the</strong>se principles and practices, policy recommendationsare introduced in Section 7.The basic principles <strong>for</strong> inclusivere<strong>for</strong>mBoth promotion of change - and management ofchangeThe most successful countries, in terms of productiveemployment, are using a mix of economicand social policies, implemented with flexibilityand designed <strong>for</strong> security. Within <strong>the</strong> context ofcompetition, specialisation and free trade, thisapproach helps to promote change and productivity;it also helps in <strong>the</strong> management of changeand in <strong>the</strong> creation of decent w<strong>ork</strong> opportunities,a sense of inclusion and a widely shared prosperity.The mix has varied from country to country,and <strong>the</strong> different policies are adjusted occasionallyto improve <strong>the</strong> synergy between economicand social policies, decent w<strong>ork</strong> and inclusion.Both property rights - and labour rightsThe report from World Commission on <strong>the</strong> SocialDimension of Globalisation argued that in<strong>for</strong>malactivities should be trans<strong>for</strong>med and integratedinto a growing <strong>for</strong>mal sector that provides decentjobs, incomes and protection. A balanced approachto upgrading <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy wouldrequire <strong>the</strong> systematic extension of propertyrights, accompanied by similar action on corelabour rights <strong>for</strong> all persons engaged in in<strong>for</strong>malactivities. The report argues that such a trans<strong>for</strong>mationis an essential part of a national strategyto reduce poverty and promote inclusion. Whileit suggests that <strong>the</strong> key to empowering <strong>the</strong> poorthrough property rights is <strong>the</strong> provision of legalidentity to <strong>the</strong>ir assets, it also advances <strong>the</strong>understanding that <strong>the</strong> key to <strong>the</strong>ir empowermentthrough labour rights lies in conferring upon<strong>the</strong>m a legal identity as w<strong>ork</strong>ers or entrepreneurs,<strong>the</strong>reby making disguised commercial or employmentrelationships visible.Both protection - and fl exibilityThe World Development Report 2006, entitledEquity and Development, recognises <strong>the</strong> intrinsicvalue of equity and makes <strong>the</strong> case <strong>for</strong> investingin people, expanding access to justice, land, andinfrastructure, and promoting fairness in markets.The report asks whe<strong>the</strong>r labour market institutionscan be designed to be pro-growth and pro-166


equity. The key to success is to link employmentcreation with protection. This requires buildingbroad societal consensus <strong>for</strong> coordinated re<strong>for</strong>msacross a variety of labour market institutions andprovision <strong>for</strong> support to w<strong>ork</strong>ers in re-entering <strong>the</strong>labour market following investments in educationand training, in incentives that would encouragemobility, and in job creation, among o<strong>the</strong>rmeasures.Lessons from national re<strong>for</strong>m practiceThere are lessons to be learned from countrieswhich recently have introduced policies aimedat empowering w<strong>ork</strong>ers and entrepreneurs in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.Legal identityLegal identity, as w<strong>ork</strong>er or entrepreneur, isof fundamental importance <strong>for</strong> legal empowerment.Some countries have tried to establish<strong>the</strong>se identities and make <strong>the</strong> employmentrelationships explicit (in labour laws or in <strong>the</strong>irextensions). Thailand provides an example of how<strong>the</strong> labour law has been extended to home w<strong>ork</strong>ersthrough a ministerial regulation. In this case,home w<strong>ork</strong>ers are considered ‘employees’ thosewho use raw materials and tools that come from<strong>the</strong> employer. The Ministerial Regulation also affirms<strong>the</strong> application of <strong>the</strong> Fundamental principlesand rights at w<strong>ork</strong> to <strong>the</strong>se w<strong>ork</strong>ers (SeeCase 1, Annex 2). Employment relationships havealso been determined through judicial decisions.In <strong>the</strong> Philippines, <strong>the</strong> Supreme Court has applieda four-fold test in determining <strong>the</strong> existenceof an employer-employee relationship: 76 ‘(1) <strong>the</strong>selection and engagement of <strong>the</strong> employee; (2)<strong>the</strong> payment of wages; (3) <strong>the</strong> power of dismissal;and (4) <strong>the</strong> power to control <strong>the</strong> employee’sconduct.’ Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> evidence of payment— through a pay slip — has been accepted asproof of employer-employee relationship (SeeCase 2, Annex 2). India offers an example of awelfare fund where <strong>the</strong> trade unions provide acertification of <strong>the</strong> eligibility of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>er. Theidentity <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e comes from membership in atrade union (See Case 3).Voice and representationThe right to voice and representation is as importantas legal identity. Throughout <strong>the</strong> world, tradeunions are launching and supporting campaigns<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> representation and protection of in<strong>for</strong>malw<strong>ork</strong>ers. For example, <strong>the</strong> Inter-American RegionalOrganisation of W<strong>ork</strong>ers has issued guidelinesand manuals to enhance organisation and representationof w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. TheAlliance <strong>for</strong> Zambia In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy Associationswas launched in 2002 in partnership with<strong>the</strong> Zambia Congress of Trade Unions. 77The Self-Employed Women’s Association (SEWA),India, is <strong>the</strong> well-known and very promising tradeunion of women in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers who actively engagein collective bargaining and o<strong>the</strong>rwise leverageinfluence over <strong>the</strong> environment in which <strong>the</strong>yw<strong>ork</strong> (See Case 4). Over <strong>the</strong> past two decades,SEWA has co-founded and inspired a number o<strong>for</strong>ganisations of in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers which individuallyand collectively are gaining voice and representationin relevant policymaking <strong>for</strong>a.In Ghana, <strong>the</strong> ILO’s Decent W<strong>ork</strong> programme hasw<strong>ork</strong>ed with local government to promote socialdialogue by creating District Assembly Sub-Committeeson Productive and Gainful Employmentthat include representatives of in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises,in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers, <strong>the</strong> private sector, andgovernment. In <strong>the</strong> Philippines, local developmentcouncils are mandated on <strong>the</strong> regional,provincial, municipal and village-level wheredifferent interest groups, including registered andaccredited local organisations, are represented.167


The Homeless People’s Federation Philippines,HPFP, participates in various municipal and village-leveldevelopment councils, including a fewlocal housing councils (See Case 5).Social protection re<strong>for</strong>mRe<strong>for</strong>m of <strong>the</strong> social protection system is astrategic way to empower people. In India in2002, <strong>the</strong> National Commission on Labour proposeda national bill <strong>for</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> unorganised(in<strong>for</strong>mal) sector with <strong>the</strong> objective of regulating‘<strong>the</strong> employment and conditions of serviceof unorganised sector w<strong>ork</strong>ers and to provide <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong>ir safety, social security, health and welfare’.The bill provides <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> establishment of W<strong>ork</strong>ers’Facilitation Centres to support and assistunorganised w<strong>ork</strong>ers, provides <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> setting upin <strong>the</strong> states of an Unorganised Sector W<strong>ork</strong>ers’Welfare Fund, with funds from government andcontributions by employers and registered w<strong>ork</strong>ers;and sets out minimum conditions of service,including hours of w<strong>ork</strong> and minimum wages (SeeCase 6). In India in 2007, <strong>the</strong> National Commissionon Enterprises in <strong>the</strong> Unorganised Sector(NCEUS) has drafted and proposed two nationalbills on <strong>the</strong> conditions of w<strong>ork</strong> and social securityof w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> unorganised (in<strong>for</strong>mal) sector:one <strong>for</strong> agricultural w<strong>ork</strong>ers, <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong> non-agriculturalw<strong>ork</strong>ers. Both bills incorporate provisions<strong>for</strong> regulating <strong>the</strong> conditions of w<strong>ork</strong> andsocial security of in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers. The statutoryNational Social Security Scheme proposed by <strong>the</strong>NCEUS consists of <strong>the</strong> following package of minimumbenefits: illness, hospitalisation, maternity,disability and life insurance, and old age pension.O<strong>the</strong>r promising examples of extending socialprotection to in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers are from Ghanaand <strong>the</strong> Philippines. In Ghana, with joint supportfrom <strong>the</strong> government and ILO’s Decent W<strong>ork</strong> programme,associations and individuals who havejoined local credit unions are encouraged to enrolin <strong>the</strong> National Health Insurance Programme.In <strong>the</strong> Philippines, <strong>the</strong> statutory social securitysystem (SSS) and <strong>the</strong> health insurance schemeshave been progressively made universal throughvoluntary schemes that are open to self-employedw<strong>ork</strong>ers through lower-priced packages and awider netw<strong>ork</strong> of collection units, including banksand organised groups (See Case 7). Notableexamples are also found in Latin America; <strong>the</strong>yinclude ef<strong>for</strong>ts in Mexico to extend social securitycoverage to <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector; innovations in socialcoverage of <strong>the</strong> Solidario programme in Chile;first rights-based health coverage in Chile, andconditional cash transfers in some 14 countriesbeginning with Brazil and Mexico.Improvement of <strong>the</strong> quality of labour marketinstitutionsSeveral countries have introduced re<strong>for</strong>ms to improve<strong>the</strong> quality of labour market institutions. In2006, Chile introduced a re<strong>for</strong>m in subcontractingprocedures to include more w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>for</strong>mallabour rights arrangements. The objective is topromote subcontracting, while at <strong>the</strong> same timeensuring compliance with all <strong>the</strong> labour obligations.The law introduced a <strong>for</strong>mal arrangementbetween subcontractors and <strong>the</strong> main firms tomeet a set of labour obligations. Direct responsibilitylies with <strong>the</strong> subcontractor, but <strong>the</strong> mainfirm has <strong>the</strong> right to demand from <strong>the</strong> subcontractora certificate of compliance issued by <strong>the</strong>labour inspectorate agency and has <strong>the</strong> right towithhold payments from subcontractors in casesin which <strong>the</strong>re are pending obligations vis-à-vis<strong>the</strong>ir w<strong>ork</strong>ers (See Case 8).Spain has over <strong>the</strong> last 20-25 years introduced aseries of re<strong>for</strong>ms of its once highly-regulated systemin an attempt to better balance <strong>the</strong> demandsof an open market economy with <strong>the</strong> needs of168


w<strong>ork</strong>s, first by allowing <strong>for</strong> an increase in <strong>the</strong>use of fixed-term contracts, <strong>the</strong>n by reintroducingconstraints in <strong>the</strong> use of temporary contractswhile easing employment protection legislation<strong>for</strong> permanent w<strong>ork</strong>ers. More recently Spanishtrade unions, employer organisations and governmentsigned an agreement to bring <strong>the</strong> use offixed-term w<strong>ork</strong> contracts more in line with <strong>the</strong>European social model (See Case 9).Legal empowerment through alternative disputeresolutionFor poor people around <strong>the</strong> world, getting accessto courts and legal support to protect<strong>the</strong>ir rights is often impossible. In many cases,<strong>the</strong> reason <strong>for</strong> this is straight<strong>for</strong>ward — <strong>the</strong>y cannotaf<strong>for</strong>d to pay <strong>the</strong> legal fees. In Tajikistan, <strong>the</strong>UK has helped to solve this problem by supportingThird Party Arbitration Courts. These courtsare an alternative way of resolving disputes: twosides to a dispute agree to nominate a third partywho <strong>the</strong>y both trust to mediate <strong>the</strong>ir disagreementand come to a decision. Although <strong>the</strong>y operateindependently of <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal legal system, decisionsare recognised by Tajikistan’s official courts.Third Party Arbitration Courts provide poor peoplewith a cheap, fair and accessible way of resolvingdisputes and protecting <strong>the</strong>ir rights. Third PartyArbitration has helped to make legal servicesavailable to 800,000 people in Tajikistan. Theapproach has also been used successfully in Russia,Kyrgyzstan, Moldova, Ukraine and Georgia(See Case 10).Improved business environmentThe World Bank Investment Climate Survey illustrates<strong>the</strong> need to improve <strong>the</strong> business environmentto encourage investment, entrepreneurshipand w<strong>ork</strong>ers rights. Many countries have foundnew ways to support SMEs through various initiativeswith <strong>the</strong> aim of upgrading <strong>the</strong>m into <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mal economy (See Chapter 4 <strong>for</strong> examples).Simplifi cation of contracting proceduresThe Senegalese Government provides an exampleof a pro-active policy of contracting out publicinfrastructure projects to small scale contractors.In this case, bidding procedures and documentshave been substantially simplified in order topermit smaller contractors to participate in <strong>the</strong>bidding process. Bureaucratic documentation isalso minimised and bidding documents containofficial unit cost estimate in order to guide <strong>the</strong>less sophisticated contractor. A general session isheld wherein contractors are told about <strong>the</strong> existenceof <strong>the</strong> implementing agency and in<strong>for</strong>medabout procedures, from <strong>the</strong> bidding to <strong>the</strong> awardingand implementation. Simplification of <strong>the</strong>process goes as far as making <strong>the</strong> name of <strong>the</strong>winner very clear in <strong>the</strong> announcement so thateven an illiterate contractor’s representative canreadily determine who was awarded <strong>the</strong> contract(See Case 11).There are also lessons to be learned from countriesthat have recently introduced policies aimedat empowering w<strong>ork</strong>ers and entrepreneurs in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy through business rights (SeeChapter 4).169


Conclusions <strong>for</strong> national strategies <strong>for</strong>legal empowermentThe examples noted above illustrate how differentpolicies can be used to provide w<strong>ork</strong>ing peoplewith: Identity (India, <strong>the</strong> Philippines, Thailand);Voice and representation (India); Social protection(Brazil, Chile, Ghana, India, Mexico, <strong>the</strong>Philippines), and New ways to resolve disputes(Tajikistan).These examples also demonstrate how differentpolicies can be used to improve <strong>the</strong> functioningof labour market institutions (Chile andThailand), and how <strong>the</strong>y can w<strong>ork</strong> to adjust <strong>the</strong>balance between protection and flexibility inresponse to changing realities (Spain).These and many o<strong>the</strong>r illustrations show thatre<strong>for</strong>m is under way. O<strong>the</strong>r countries can use <strong>the</strong>examples and principles presented can be usedby o<strong>the</strong>r countries in <strong>the</strong>ir ef<strong>for</strong>t to design strategies<strong>for</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. Thereis a need <strong>for</strong> global action to convert <strong>the</strong>se ‘goodnews’ approaches into a global movement.7. Towards a new socialcontract: Policiesand Processes <strong>for</strong> LegalEmpowermentPolicy recommendationsBuilding on an emerging global social contract— <strong>the</strong> broad support <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Fundamental Principlesand Rights at W<strong>ork</strong> and <strong>the</strong> Decent W<strong>ork</strong>agenda — we recommend that <strong>the</strong> Commissionendorse <strong>the</strong> following priorities <strong>for</strong> legal empowermentof those living and w<strong>ork</strong>ing in poverty:• Streng<strong>the</strong>n identity, voice, representation anddialogue. The process of legal empowermentstarts with identity. Just as property and physicalassets of <strong>the</strong> poor are recognised, so alsomust <strong>the</strong> greatest asset of <strong>the</strong> poor, namely<strong>the</strong>ir labour and human capital, be effectivelyrecognised. There is a particular need toensure that w<strong>ork</strong>ers and entrepreneurs in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy have <strong>the</strong> right to freedom ofassociation through organisations of <strong>the</strong>ir ownchoosing and to collective bargaining, particularlywomen and youth who are over-representedin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Emphasis shouldbe placed on building up representativeorganisations of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor, particularlywage w<strong>ork</strong>ers and self-employed operating in<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, to have voice, representationand dialogue with <strong>for</strong>mal economyoperators and with public authorities in orderto defend <strong>the</strong>ir rights.• Streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> quality of labour regulationand <strong>the</strong> effective en<strong>for</strong>cement of fundamentalprinciples and rights at w<strong>ork</strong>. The purpose isto create synergies between protection andproductivity of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor and of <strong>the</strong>irassets. Reviewing <strong>the</strong> quality of institutions170


and of regulations should involve a critical andself-critical review of legal instruments from<strong>the</strong> point of view of <strong>the</strong>ir impacts on productivityand on <strong>the</strong> protection of labour.• Support application of a minimum packageof labour rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Theaim should be that every country strives <strong>for</strong> aminimum floor <strong>for</strong> empowerment that is realisticand en<strong>for</strong>ceable, as a basis to graduallystreng<strong>the</strong>n and extend application of standards,taking into account productivity levelsand o<strong>the</strong>r national circumstances. To this aima package of labour rights is proposed <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy that upholds <strong>the</strong> Declarationon Fundamental Principles and Rightsat W<strong>ork</strong> and three crucial aspects related tow<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions: (1) health and safety atw<strong>ork</strong>; (2) hours of w<strong>ork</strong>, and (3) minimumincome. It must be recognised that labourstandards at this minimum level constitutea basic floor <strong>for</strong> empowerment beyond whichprogressive, ra<strong>the</strong>r than full, compliance isexpected. That is, we propose to build upprogressively from this basic floor throughinstitutional approaches that are feasible even<strong>for</strong> production units with limited capacity <strong>for</strong>compliance. Strategies can aim at progressivecompliance and gradual convergence into aunified set of w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions, as a goal.Some of <strong>the</strong> standards such as occupationalsafety and health can be improved immediatelyat a low cost. O<strong>the</strong>rs can be achievedgradually through a developmental process ofawareness raising and capacity building.• Streng<strong>the</strong>n access to opportunities <strong>for</strong> decentw<strong>ork</strong> and to opportunities <strong>for</strong> education,training and retraining, as well as combatingdiscrimination to ensure efficient labourmarkets. This priority aims to promote changeand dynamism, linking private initiative withpublic policy so as to expand employment in agrowing and inclusive economy. Labour rights,to be effective, should not exclude <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ingpoor, nor constrain <strong>the</strong>ir creative and entrepreneurialpotential. Opportunities <strong>for</strong> educationand capacity building as well as measures <strong>for</strong>combating discrimination help increase legalrecognition of <strong>the</strong> poor and bring <strong>the</strong>m closerto such economic opportunities. The reorganisationof production and distribution throughsub-contracting and outsourcing is associatedwith <strong>the</strong> expansion of in<strong>for</strong>mal employment in<strong>the</strong> supply chains. Private and public procurementrepresents, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, a practical yetstrategic policy lever through which to upgrade<strong>the</strong> productivity, incomes and w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditionsof <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor. Integrating employmentcreation, labour rights and decent w<strong>ork</strong>into public and private procurement practicesis <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e a key mechanism to legally empower<strong>the</strong> poor. Often solutions to poverty andin<strong>for</strong>mality can be found outside as well aswithin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Policies to createand provide improved access of <strong>the</strong> poorto new opportunities <strong>for</strong> full, productive andfreely chosen employment, as promoted in ILOConvention 122, can provide a key mechanism<strong>for</strong> empowering <strong>the</strong> poor in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy and facilitating <strong>the</strong>ir transition to<strong>for</strong>mality.• Support inclusive social protection. Therecognition of <strong>the</strong> rights to social security hasbeen developed through universally acceptedinstruments, such as <strong>the</strong> Universal Declarationof Human Rights and <strong>the</strong> InternationalCovenant on Economic Social and CulturalRights, which proclaim that social security isa fundamental societal right to which everyhuman is entitled. This promise must beupheld by all countries through laws, institu-171


tions and responsive mechanisms that couldprotect <strong>the</strong> poor from shocks and contingenciesthat can impoverish, and measures thatguarantee access to medical care, healthinsurance, old age pensions, and socialservices. These mechanisms must not besolely dependent on <strong>the</strong> evidence of employmentstatus but must be open to all types ofw<strong>ork</strong>ers. From a systemic perspective, rightsto pensions and health protection should begranted to <strong>the</strong> people as citizens ra<strong>the</strong>r thanas w<strong>ork</strong>ers, and <strong>the</strong>y should be awarded onuniversality principles.We also recommend <strong>the</strong> following specific actionsfavouring legal empowerment:• Ensure that legal empowerment becomes adriver <strong>for</strong> gender equality. Poverty has a genderdimension, and legal empowerment can helpdrive gender equality. A key challenge is toensure that ILO labour standards which promoteequality of opportunity and treatment areeffectively extended to in<strong>for</strong>mal sector w<strong>ork</strong>ers.78 The starting point <strong>for</strong> this process may befound in <strong>the</strong> core labour standards on genderequality, namely, <strong>the</strong> Equal RemunerationConvention, no.100, 1951; <strong>the</strong> Convention onDiscrimination (Employment and Occupation),no. 111, 1958. Much useful guidance can befound in <strong>the</strong> 1996 ILO Home W<strong>ork</strong> Convention79 which mandates <strong>the</strong> extension of legalprotection and legal empowerment to homew<strong>ork</strong>ers, who are predominantly women. Genderis already a mainstream priority in <strong>the</strong> integrationof Decent W<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong> PRSP w<strong>ork</strong>. Specificcapacity-building ef<strong>for</strong>ts have in particularbeen made in Bolivia, Brazil, Ecuador, Ethiopia,Honduras, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay andYemen to influence Poverty Reduction Strategies(PRSs) at <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mulation stage. A morein-depth process has been recently launchedto fur<strong>the</strong>r consolidate gender and employmentin three country PRS processes, namely inBurkina Faso, Liberia and <strong>the</strong> United Republicof Tanzania. This integrated approach includesenhancing <strong>the</strong> capacity of constituents <strong>for</strong>mainstreaming gender equality in employment;facilitating gender budgeting of projected employmentprogrammes in <strong>the</strong> PRS action plans;building partnerships with o<strong>the</strong>r organisationsat national and international levels, which areinvolved in promoting gender equality in PRS.• Support legal empowerment <strong>for</strong> indigenouspeople. The ILO Indigenous and Tribal PeoplesConvention provides guidance and strategies<strong>for</strong> legal empowerment with respect not onlyto labour rights and protection of employment,but also with respect to land and propertyrights. Special ef<strong>for</strong>ts <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir legal empowermentare demonstrated in an ‘ethnic audit’undertaken of 14 PRSPs as well as casestudies of country processes in Bolivia, Cambodia,Cameroon, Guatemala and Nepal. Theresearch clearly showed that, although indigenouspeoples are disproportionately representedamong <strong>the</strong> poor, <strong>the</strong>ir needs and prioritiesare generally not reflected in <strong>the</strong> strategiesemployed to combat poverty. Ano<strong>the</strong>r contributionis research produced by <strong>the</strong> ILO anddebated at <strong>the</strong> United Nations PermanentForum on Indigenous Issues and within <strong>the</strong>Inter-Agency Support Group. Subsequently,<strong>the</strong> World Bank organised an InternationalConference on Indigenous Peoples and PovertyReduction (New Y<strong>ork</strong>, May 2006) and committedto w<strong>ork</strong> towards <strong>the</strong> practical inclusion ofindigenous peoples’ concerns in <strong>the</strong> PRSPs ina selected number of pilot countries in Africa,Asia and Latin America.172


Process recommendationsOur w<strong>ork</strong>ing group recommends that <strong>the</strong>Commission consider <strong>the</strong> following policyprocesses and institutional champions <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>implementation of its recommendations on legalempowerment through labour rights.• Promote national development framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong>legal empowerment and decent w<strong>ork</strong>. Nationalgovernments and parliaments are responsible<strong>for</strong> labour rights and social conditions andbear a major responsibility <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m andeffectiveness of national labour market institutions.The Decent W<strong>ork</strong> Agenda proposes avalue-based framew<strong>ork</strong> that is best definedat <strong>the</strong> national level through social dialogue.It does not propose a one-size-fits-all solution,nor imply conditionality of any type. Themix and sequencing of policy actions are tobe defined locally, taking account of diversityin <strong>the</strong> level of development, including financial,human, and institutional capacities, andimplemented through cooperation betweengovernment, business, w<strong>ork</strong>ers and society.The intrinsic value of <strong>the</strong> Decent W<strong>ork</strong> Agendais to make employment a central goal of economicpolicies and progressive improvementin <strong>the</strong> quality of w<strong>ork</strong>, including labour rightsand returns to labour as <strong>the</strong> main strategy <strong>for</strong>moving people out of poverty. Decent W<strong>ork</strong>Country Programmes (DWCPs) are <strong>the</strong> maintool <strong>for</strong> driving this re<strong>for</strong>m process <strong>for</strong>ward inpartnership with all national and internationalinstitutions. DWCPs contribute to internationaldevelopment framew<strong>ork</strong>s such as povertyreduction strategies, national Millennium DevelopmentGoal strategies, <strong>the</strong> United NationsDevelopment Assistance Framew<strong>ork</strong> (UNDAF),and o<strong>the</strong>r integrated development plans.• Mobilise <strong>the</strong> Development Banks to supportnational re<strong>for</strong>m programmes. Re<strong>for</strong>m strategiesto include employment and labour rightswill need to be adapted to regional and localpriorities. There<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong> Regional DevelopmentBanks, Political Organisations and UN organisationscan be tapped as institutional champions<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m agenda on legal empowerment.Development Banks need to make legalempowerment a top priority, integrating accessto justice, property rights, labour rights andbusiness rights in one comprehensive strategy<strong>for</strong> good governance of markets, to supportnational re<strong>for</strong>m processes. They need to seek<strong>the</strong> support from regional political authoritiesand from <strong>the</strong> UN regional organisations.• Mobilise <strong>the</strong> principal actors of <strong>the</strong> global system,particularly <strong>the</strong> World Bank and <strong>the</strong> ILO,to w<strong>ork</strong> better toge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong> decent w<strong>ork</strong>. Two of<strong>the</strong> main global actors in <strong>the</strong> field of w<strong>ork</strong> anddevelopment, <strong>the</strong> ILO and <strong>the</strong> World Bank,have both contributed by developing instruments<strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m, <strong>the</strong> World Bank’s PRSs and<strong>the</strong> ILO DWCPs. A key to a successful re<strong>for</strong>mprocess at <strong>the</strong> national level is better policycoherence at <strong>the</strong> global level. Legal empowermentand re<strong>for</strong>m of labour rights require closeco-operation between governments, employersand w<strong>ork</strong>ers, nationally and locally. Theywill need support in many <strong>for</strong>ms from <strong>the</strong>leading global institutions to build capacity.The common goal should be to make labourmarkets w<strong>ork</strong> better — more efficient andmore equitable — <strong>for</strong> both w<strong>ork</strong>ers and smallbusinesses.• Support voluntary initiatives <strong>for</strong> legal empowermentthrough labour rights. Codes of conductconstitute a strategy <strong>for</strong> motivating improvementsof <strong>the</strong> per<strong>for</strong>mance of multinationalcorporations. An increasing number of <strong>the</strong>m,including that of <strong>the</strong> Ethical Trade Initiative,are based on ILO’s core labour standards, par-173


ticularly <strong>the</strong> prohibition of <strong>for</strong>ced labour, childlabour and discrimination in <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong> place.These codes of conduct initiatives are alreadyplaying an important role, as businesses havebecome more sensitive and responsive to <strong>the</strong>concerns of ethical consumers.• Mobilise donor countries to promote legal empowermentand decent w<strong>ork</strong>. Donor countriescould do a lot to support legal empowermentand <strong>the</strong> inclusion of a decent w<strong>ork</strong> agenda inregional and national strategies. For example,<strong>the</strong> EU is supporting <strong>the</strong> integration of decentw<strong>ork</strong> goals in national PRS processes in 60countries.• Promote a better understanding of <strong>the</strong> costsand benefits of legal empowerment throughdecent w<strong>ork</strong>. The costs and benefits of undertakingre<strong>for</strong>ming legal empowerment throughlabour rights and decent w<strong>ork</strong> need to beaddressed. The first basic question is what are<strong>the</strong> expected benefits of such re<strong>for</strong>m on productivityand <strong>the</strong>reby on prosperity. The mainpurpose of re<strong>for</strong>m is to improve <strong>the</strong> qualityof labour market institutions and <strong>the</strong>reby <strong>the</strong>functioning of labour markets. Such re<strong>for</strong>ms,provided <strong>the</strong>y are well designed, should beseen as likely to enhance productivity. Nonaction,or maintaining <strong>the</strong> status quo, shouldbe seen as leaving a burden on <strong>the</strong> economy.With income inequality growing ever largerwith worrying implications <strong>for</strong> sustainablesocieties, an ambitious re<strong>for</strong>m programmeintegrating Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorshould be seen as a necessity, not a luxury.The second basic question is <strong>the</strong> cost of startingand sustaining <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m process and <strong>the</strong>af<strong>for</strong>dability of related policy initiatives. Thereis no simple answer to that question. Therewill be initial costs that have to be fundedmainly through restructuring of public expenditureprogrammes. The amount of costs and<strong>the</strong> pay-back in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of higher quality oflabour market institutions will probably varybetween states, depending on policy designand <strong>the</strong> success of <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m process. A successfulstrategy <strong>for</strong> integrating w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy — through, <strong>for</strong> example,integrating employment creation programmeswith social protection systems - will broaden<strong>the</strong> tax base and decrease unemployment,underemployment, decent w<strong>ork</strong> deficits, ando<strong>the</strong>r social costs, so that initial costs willsoon be outweighed by benefits.• Streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> statistical base <strong>for</strong> legalempowerment. 80 Labour <strong>for</strong>ce and o<strong>the</strong>reconomic statistics need to be improved tofully capture <strong>the</strong> size and contribution of <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Although estimates of <strong>the</strong>size and (less so) contribution of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy are available in a growing number ofcountries, all <strong>for</strong>ms of in<strong>for</strong>mal employment- especially women’s home-based productionand disguised wage employment - are not yetfully visible in <strong>the</strong> official national statisticsused to in<strong>for</strong>mal national policies. The legalempowerment strategy must, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e,include ef<strong>for</strong>ts to make visible all <strong>for</strong>ms of in<strong>for</strong>malemployment. This should include makingdisguised employment relationships moreexplicit; it should also make more visible both<strong>the</strong> invisible supply chain and home-basedproduction. Our w<strong>ork</strong>ing group recommendsthat improved labour <strong>for</strong>ce and economic statisticsbe a priority goal <strong>for</strong> national statisticalservices and be incorporated into <strong>the</strong> MillenniumDevelopment Indicators.174


Towards a New Social Contract.There is a tripartite consensus from employer,w<strong>ork</strong>er and government representatives on <strong>the</strong>need <strong>for</strong> a <strong>for</strong>mal and effective legal systemwith guarantees <strong>for</strong> all citizens and enterprisesthat contracts are honoured and upheld, <strong>the</strong>rule of <strong>the</strong> law is respected and property rightsare secure. Such a legal system is a key conditionnot only <strong>for</strong> attracting investment, but also<strong>for</strong> generating certainty, and nurturing trust andfairness in society. 81 The growing recognition of<strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> labour rights to catalyse employmentcreation in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, while protectingits w<strong>ork</strong>ers, has now led to an emerging globalsocial contract, a broad agenda <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m and<strong>for</strong> empowerment. Labour rights, business rights,property rights and business rights taken toge<strong>the</strong>rcan <strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> basis of this new social contract.Our W<strong>ork</strong>ing Group <strong>for</strong> Chapter 3 suggests that<strong>the</strong> underpinnings of <strong>the</strong> new social contract onlabour rights include five fundamental areas ofaction, namely:- Streng<strong>the</strong>n identity, voice, representation anddialogue.- Streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> quality of labour regulationand <strong>the</strong> effective en<strong>for</strong>cement of fundamentalprinciples and rights at w<strong>ork</strong>.proposals are firmly based in <strong>the</strong> international humanrights tradition. Human rights are <strong>the</strong> basis<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Social contract. It is <strong>the</strong> obligation of <strong>the</strong>state as <strong>the</strong> primary duty bearer to protect andpromote <strong>the</strong>se rights.• We use <strong>the</strong> word ‘contract’ to emphasise mutualresponsibility. The state has a duty to protectand <strong>the</strong> citizens have <strong>the</strong> right to protection— and obligations, which follow <strong>the</strong>reof.Employers and employees are also tied bymutual obligations. And large businesses havea duty not to exploit smaller businesses withwhich <strong>the</strong>y have production or distributionties.• We use <strong>the</strong> word ‘global’ to emphasise <strong>the</strong> roleand responsibility of <strong>the</strong> actors at <strong>the</strong> international,regional, national and local levels.• We use <strong>the</strong> word ‘social’ to emphasise that <strong>the</strong>aim of this initiative is to improve <strong>the</strong> socialconditions of people in poor countries, including:income, health, education, w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions.• We have put ‘Towards’ be<strong>for</strong>e a Global SocialContract in <strong>the</strong> title of this report to emphasisdevelopment, process and time horizons.- Support application of a minimum package oflabour rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.- Streng<strong>the</strong>n access to opportunities <strong>for</strong> decentw<strong>ork</strong> and to opportunities <strong>for</strong> education, trainingand retraining, as well as combating discriminationto ensure efficient labour markets.- Support inclusive social protection.We recommend a new departure in internationaldevelopment strategies, centred on <strong>the</strong> DecentW<strong>ork</strong> agenda as a Global Social Contract. Our175


Annex 1:Recent and current initiatives toimprove statistics on <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomyWhat is clear from <strong>the</strong> statistics presented inthis Report is that <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy isfar larger than most people recognise. However,<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy is still undercounted andundervalued in most countries. Few countries collect<strong>the</strong> statistics needed to fully capture all <strong>for</strong>msof in<strong>for</strong>mal employment, both self-employmentand wage employment. Reflecting <strong>the</strong> assumptionsunderlying labour regulations and labour economics,- notably, <strong>the</strong> presumption of an explicit employer-employeerelationship — labour <strong>for</strong>ce ando<strong>the</strong>r economic statistics do not always reflect <strong>the</strong>full range of w<strong>ork</strong> arrangements and employmentstatuses.To generate more accurate and comprehensive statisticson in<strong>for</strong>mal employment and labour marketsmore generally, it is necessary to improve statisticalconcepts and methods, including:• An expanded set of place of w<strong>ork</strong> indicators,including w<strong>ork</strong> at home, on <strong>the</strong> street, in fields,in <strong>for</strong>ests, in waterways, or in <strong>the</strong> open air;• An expanded set of employment status indicators,including all types of self-employment,wage employment, and intermediary ambiguouscategories (such as independent contractorsand industrial outw<strong>ork</strong>ers);• Data on <strong>the</strong> socio-economic status of differentcategories of w<strong>ork</strong>ers, including: level of earnings;legal status: contract versus no contract,registered versus non-registered; w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions;and social protection coverage by typeand source (health insurance, old age pensions,disability insurance, unemployment insurance,life insurance, maternity, child care);Improved statistics would help to focus <strong>the</strong> attentionof policymakers on <strong>the</strong> economic contributionsof <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy and <strong>the</strong> linkagesbetween in<strong>for</strong>mal employment and poverty. Morespecifically, improved labour-<strong>for</strong>ce statistics thatcapture all <strong>for</strong>ms of in<strong>for</strong>mal employment wouldserve to:• Increase <strong>the</strong> visibility of those who w<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, especially <strong>the</strong> least visibleand most vulnerable w<strong>ork</strong>ers;• Advance understanding of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy,including its contribution to economicgrowth and its links with poverty;• In<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> design of appropriate legal re<strong>for</strong>msand policies <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy.Ideally, a unified framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> data collectionwould be developed — one that allows <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>classification, comparison, and analysis of <strong>the</strong>full set of employment statuses and w<strong>ork</strong> arrangementsthat exist in both developed and developingcountries.Fortunately, <strong>the</strong>re are a number of recent and currentinitiatives to improve statistics on <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy. The 2002 International Labour Conferenceand <strong>the</strong> 2003 International Conference ofLabour Statisticians have endorsed an expandedstatistical definition of in<strong>for</strong>mal employment thatincludes self-employment in in<strong>for</strong>mal (small unregistered)enterprises and wage employment inin<strong>for</strong>mal (unprotected) jobs, The ILO Bureau ofStatistics, <strong>the</strong> International Expert Group on In<strong>for</strong>malSector Statistics (Delhi Group), and <strong>the</strong> globalnetw<strong>ork</strong> Women in In<strong>for</strong>mal Employment: Globalisingand Organising (WIEGO) are jointly producinga manual on surveys of in<strong>for</strong>mal employmentso defined (<strong>for</strong>thcoming in 2008). The Sub-Group176


on Gender Indicators of <strong>the</strong> Inter-Agency and ExpertGroup (IAEG) on MDG Indicators and <strong>the</strong> TaskForce on MDG #3 (Education and Gender Equality)have endorsed an indicator on <strong>the</strong> ‘structureof employment by type and sex’ developed by <strong>the</strong>ILO Bureau of Statistics and WIEGO and a growingnumber of countries are using this indicatorto compile and present <strong>the</strong>ir national labour <strong>for</strong>cedata. The System of National Accounts is currentlyrevising its chapter on measuring <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sectorcontribution to GDP.The donor community should support <strong>the</strong>se initiativesto improve labour <strong>for</strong>ce and economic statisticsand national governments should use <strong>the</strong>expanded statistical definition and related statisticalmethods in <strong>the</strong>ir collection of labour <strong>for</strong>ce ando<strong>the</strong>r economic statistics.Annex 2:Country case experiencesCase 1:Extending Thailand’s labour lawthrough <strong>the</strong> Ministerial Regulation <strong>for</strong>home w<strong>ork</strong>ers 82In Thailand, in 2004-05, <strong>the</strong> Ministry of Labourtook <strong>the</strong> initiative of drawing up ministerial regulationsto extend <strong>the</strong> reach of <strong>the</strong> labour law tohome w<strong>ork</strong>ers and agricultural w<strong>ork</strong>ers. Homebasedw<strong>ork</strong>ers are defined as having <strong>the</strong> followingcharacteristics:1. They receive contracts from an employer to produce,assemble, repair or process;2. They w<strong>ork</strong> at a location that is not <strong>the</strong> establishmentof <strong>the</strong> employer;3. They w<strong>ork</strong> to earn a wage;4. They use all or part of raw materials or productioninstruments of <strong>the</strong> employer;5. They are contracted to w<strong>ork</strong> at home, and <strong>the</strong>w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>the</strong>y do is a part or all of <strong>the</strong> productionprocess or business of <strong>the</strong> employer.177Case 2:Judicial ruling on employmentrelationship in <strong>the</strong> PhilippinesThe Supreme Court in <strong>the</strong> Philippines, in landmarkdecisions, recognised an employer-employeerelationship in situations where this is ambiguous.The said Supreme Court rulings upheld <strong>the</strong> statusof w<strong>ork</strong>ers on commission, boundary, 83 piece-rateor task base and w<strong>ork</strong>ers hired through a third partysuch as a recruitment agency.In determining <strong>the</strong> existence of an employer-employeerelationship, <strong>the</strong> Supreme Court 84 applied


<strong>the</strong> following four-fold test: ‘(1) <strong>the</strong> selection andengagement of <strong>the</strong> employee; (2) <strong>the</strong> payment ofwages; (3) <strong>the</strong> power of dismissal; and (4) <strong>the</strong>power to control <strong>the</strong> employee’s conduct.’The Supreme Court insisted that, in <strong>the</strong> case oftransport operators, <strong>the</strong> owner of <strong>the</strong> public vehiclehas supervision and control over <strong>the</strong> driver.The management of <strong>the</strong> business is in <strong>the</strong> owner’shands. The owner as holder of <strong>the</strong> certificate ofpublic convenience must see to it that <strong>the</strong> driverfollows <strong>the</strong> route prescribed by <strong>the</strong> franchising authorityand <strong>the</strong> rules promulgated as regards itsoperation. The fact that <strong>the</strong> drivers do not receivefixed wages but get only that in excess of <strong>the</strong> socalled‘boundary’ <strong>the</strong>y pay to <strong>the</strong> owner/operator isnot sufficient to withdraw <strong>the</strong> relationship between<strong>the</strong>m from that of employer and employee.Case 3:Welfare fund in IndiaThere are w<strong>ork</strong>ers who would not be able to participatein a contributory, voluntary scheme, no matterhow well designed such schemes are. W<strong>ork</strong>erswho earn very little income or have seasonal w<strong>ork</strong>would not likely be able to keep up with <strong>the</strong> requiredcontributions.Recognising this constraint, several states in Indiafound a solution in taxing <strong>the</strong> revenue that <strong>the</strong>sector generates, ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> employers or <strong>the</strong>w<strong>ork</strong>ers. The funds raised from <strong>the</strong>se levies, whichare Termed ‘welfare funds’, used on <strong>the</strong> welfare of<strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ers who produce <strong>the</strong> taxed products.India uses this system <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> benefit of those whoproduce bidis (hand-rolled cigarettes), mine w<strong>ork</strong>ers,cine w<strong>ork</strong>ers and w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> building industry.The Bidi W<strong>ork</strong>ers Welfare Act (1976), <strong>for</strong> instance,provides <strong>the</strong> national labour legislation that taxes<strong>the</strong> revenue generated by <strong>the</strong> sector (but not employers)to create a welfare fund administered bygovernment. There are estimated to be over fourmillion bide w<strong>ork</strong>ers in India, 90 percent of whomare women. Most of <strong>the</strong>m w<strong>ork</strong> under a sub-contractfrom <strong>the</strong>ir homes <strong>for</strong> a low piece rate and withoutaccess to health insurance or social security.Taxes of 50 paise (or half a rupee) per 1,000 bidisare levied. The welfare fund operates hospitals anddispensaries, awards scholarships and providesschool supplies and uni<strong>for</strong>ms. Initially, <strong>the</strong> funddid not cover standard aspects of social protectionsuch as sickness, occupational injury, maternity,disability, old age or survivors and unemploymentcoverage, but it has now been extended into groupinsurance <strong>for</strong> which <strong>the</strong> welfare fund pays half.The Life Insurance Corporation Insurance Schemesubsidises <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r half. 85Welfare funds have also been set up also <strong>for</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ersin building and construction. In Tamil Nadu,a tax of 0.1 to 0.3 percent is levied on <strong>the</strong> costof all building or construction projects. This taxfinances <strong>the</strong> Tamil Nadu Scheme issued in 1994which prescribes <strong>the</strong> procedure <strong>for</strong> registeringmanual w<strong>ork</strong>ers and <strong>the</strong> supply of identity cards.It also provides <strong>for</strong> crèches to look after <strong>the</strong> babiesof women construction w<strong>ork</strong>ers, a group accidentinsurance scheme, educational assistance <strong>for</strong> sonsor daughters of registered w<strong>ork</strong>ers, assistance <strong>for</strong>marriage of <strong>the</strong> son or daughter of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>er, assistanceto meet expenses towards <strong>the</strong> delivery ofa child, assistance to families of manual w<strong>ork</strong>erswho died due to accident or natural causes, andpension to cover every w<strong>ork</strong>er who has reached 60years and has been a member continuously <strong>for</strong> fiveyears.A bill is also now pending that seeks to create asimilar welfare fund to cover <strong>the</strong> ‘unorganised sector’more broadly.178


Case 4:Collective identity, collectivebargaining and global impactIndustrial outw<strong>ork</strong>ers, whe<strong>the</strong>r in <strong>the</strong> garment,shoe, or electronic sectors, face a number of commonproblems, among <strong>the</strong>m: low piece-rates andearnings; irregularity of w<strong>ork</strong>; irregular and (often)delayed payments and <strong>the</strong> costs of providing/maintainingw<strong>ork</strong>space, utilities, and equipment.In addition, some endure harsh or dangerous w<strong>ork</strong>ingconditions — <strong>for</strong> example, shoe makers are exposedto toxic glues and many o<strong>the</strong>r w<strong>ork</strong>ers suffersore backs and deteriorating eye sight from w<strong>ork</strong>ingin badly-equipped and poorly-lit w<strong>ork</strong>places(often <strong>the</strong>ir own homes).SEWA has a long history of w<strong>ork</strong>ing with garmentw<strong>ork</strong>ers focusing primarily on negotiating higherpiece-rates and fairer w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions <strong>for</strong> garmentindustrial outw<strong>ork</strong>ers, many of whom are Muslim.These organizing ef<strong>for</strong>ts have involved negotiationswith <strong>the</strong> Labour Commissioner — as well asrallies in front of his office — to demand minimumwage, identity cards, and welfare schemes (childcare,health care, and school scholarships) <strong>for</strong> subcontractedgarment w<strong>ork</strong>ers.In 1986, SEWA was able to get a minimum wage <strong>for</strong>garment stitching (89.60 rupees per day) includedin <strong>the</strong> official Gujarat state Schedule of minimumwages under <strong>the</strong> Minimum Wages Act. 86 Over <strong>the</strong>years, SEWA has also helped ‘own account’ garmentmakers to acquire new skills, improved equipment,and market in<strong>for</strong>mation to try to compete in<strong>the</strong> fast-changing local garment market. This hasincluded loans <strong>for</strong> improved sewing machines andrelated gadgets, training at <strong>the</strong> National Institute ofFashion Technology (NIFT), and installing electricityin <strong>the</strong> homes of SEWA members (to avoid <strong>the</strong>high costs of tapping electricity illegally).In recent years, as export-oriented, factory-basedgarment production has expanded in AhmadabadCity, SEWA has begun to organise waged w<strong>ork</strong>ersin garment factories as well.During <strong>the</strong> 1980s, SEWA began establishing linkageswith membership-based organisations ofhome-based w<strong>ork</strong>ers and street vendors and NGOsw<strong>ork</strong>ing with <strong>the</strong>se groups. In <strong>the</strong> mid-1990s, attwo separate meetings in Europe, <strong>the</strong>se organisationscame toge<strong>the</strong>r under SEWA’s leadership to<strong>for</strong>m two international alliances — one of organisationsof home-based w<strong>ork</strong>ers, <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r of organisationsof street vendors.From its inception, <strong>the</strong> alliance of home-basedw<strong>ork</strong>er organisations was centrally involved in <strong>the</strong>campaign to pass an International Labour Organization(ILO) convention on home w<strong>ork</strong>. To helpwith <strong>the</strong> campaign, SEWA and its allies promotedresearch ef<strong>for</strong>ts to compile and analyse existingdata on home w<strong>ork</strong>ers worldwide, and UNIFEM wasasked to convene an Asia region policy dialogueon home w<strong>ork</strong>ers that included government representatives.With <strong>the</strong> passage of <strong>the</strong> ILO Conventionon Home W<strong>ork</strong> in 1996, SEWA and HomeNetrecognised <strong>the</strong> power of statistics and of ‘joint action’of activists, researchers, and policymakers.This recognition led to <strong>the</strong> 1997 global action-research-policynetw<strong>ork</strong> called WIEGO which servesas a think-tank <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> growing global movement ofin<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers.In 1995, SEWA organised a meeting of representativesof street vendor organisations from a dozenof cities around <strong>the</strong> world as well as activistsand lawyers w<strong>ork</strong>ing with <strong>the</strong>m at <strong>the</strong> RockefellerFoundation Study and Conference Centre in Bellagio,Italy. At that meeting, <strong>the</strong> participants drafted<strong>the</strong> Bellagio International Declaration of StreetVendors which calls <strong>for</strong> action by individual traders,traders’ associations, city governments, andinternational organisations including <strong>the</strong> United179


Nations, <strong>the</strong> ILO and <strong>the</strong> World Bank. The participantsalso called <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> establishment of an internationalnetw<strong>ork</strong> of street vendor organisationsto be called StreetNet. In early 2000, a StreetNetoffice was set up in Durban, South Africa. In November2002, after several regional meetings ofstreet vendor organisations, StreetNet Internationalwas officially launched. The aim of StreetNet isto promote <strong>the</strong> exchange of in<strong>for</strong>mation and ideason critical issues facing street vendors, marketvendors and hawkers (i.e. mobile vendors) and onpractical organising and advocacy strategies.Membership-based organisations (unions, co-operativesor associations) directly organising streetvendors, market vendors and/or hawkers among<strong>the</strong>ir members, are entitled to become affiliated toStreetNet International. As of late 2007, Street-Net International had 34 affiliates in 30 countries,including: local associations or trade unions, nationalfederations or associations, and regional alliances.Over <strong>the</strong> past decade, SEWA has also co-foundedor inspired national and regional branches ofhome w<strong>ork</strong>ers and <strong>the</strong>ir allies (called HomeNets)in South-East and South Asia, and national alliancesof street vendors in India and Kenya. It alsoserves on an international coordinating committeethat has organised three regional and two internationalconferences of organisations of in<strong>for</strong>malw<strong>ork</strong>ers; and as advisor to an international steeringcommittee that is planning <strong>the</strong> first internationalconference of organisations of waste collectors tobe held in Columbia in early 2008.Toge<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong>se organisations have helped foster aglobal movement of w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economythat now includes local trade unions and o<strong>the</strong>rmembership-based organisations of in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers,national and global trade union federations thathave begun organising in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers, severalnational federations of w<strong>ork</strong>ers’ education associations,<strong>the</strong> International Federation of W<strong>ork</strong>ers’ EducationAssociations (IFWEA), eight national andtwo regional HomeNets, StreetNet International,and <strong>the</strong> WIEGO netw<strong>ork</strong>. Drawing inspiration andguidance from SEWA, this movement continues toidentify and netw<strong>ork</strong> with organisations of in<strong>for</strong>malw<strong>ork</strong>ers and to enlighten and influence policy debateson <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.Case 5:Federation of urban poor participatingin governanceThe Homeless People’s Federation Philippines(HPFP) is a self-help, community-based federationthat promotes savings mobilisation in low-incomecommunities as a way of building <strong>the</strong>ir financialcapacity to invest in <strong>the</strong>ir own development. HPFPw<strong>ork</strong>s towards securing land tenure, upgradingsettlements and uplifting <strong>the</strong> economic status ofits members. It uses savings mainly as a strategy,not only to finance community investments butalso to bring people toge<strong>the</strong>r to w<strong>ork</strong> towards <strong>the</strong>ircommon goals. HPFP is thus not only a financialtool but also a social mechanism, which buildsnetw<strong>ork</strong>s of communities that foster continuouslearning and innovation, partnerships and supportsystems. This netw<strong>ork</strong> of communities opens upnew possibilities <strong>for</strong> negotiations with <strong>the</strong> stateand, among o<strong>the</strong>r things, <strong>the</strong> realisation of new<strong>for</strong>ms of partnership.In relation to its partnerships with public institutions,<strong>the</strong> federation deems it important to berecognised as a partner of barangays — villagelevel governance units that are <strong>the</strong> first line of engagementwith communities — and to participatein one important mechanism available to people’sorganisations and NGOs, namely <strong>the</strong> barangay developmentcouncil, where barangay physical, eco-180


nomic and social development plans and budgetsare prepared and approved. Barangay plans andprojects have a palpable impact on communities.Road projects, <strong>for</strong> example, can lead to dislocationof some communities, and health-related projectsmay overlap ra<strong>the</strong>r than complement communityinitiatedfacilities.In general, local development councils are mandatedat all levels, from <strong>the</strong> barangays up to <strong>the</strong>cities and provinces. They were created to encouragepeople’s participation in governance and<strong>the</strong>reby to promote transparency in all local governmenttransactions. The barangay developmentcouncil, in particular, is a vehicle that ensures <strong>the</strong>participation of civil society groups in <strong>the</strong> choice ofdevelopment projects and in <strong>the</strong> appropriation anduse of funds, so that <strong>the</strong>se are not <strong>the</strong> sole responsibilityof barangay officials. HPFP leaders lobbiedsuccessfully <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> activation of a barangay developmentcouncil in Quezon City, on which <strong>the</strong>reare as HPFP representatives, and HPFP leadersare also members of <strong>the</strong> city development councilof General Santos City. However, <strong>the</strong> experience of<strong>the</strong> federation is that without local pressure, <strong>the</strong>secouncils may not operate effectively and may existonly in name.Engaging government and private agencies did notcome easily to <strong>the</strong> HPFP. Communities still struggleas <strong>the</strong>y interact with government and privateentities that are not accustomed to dealing with<strong>the</strong> poor on an equal footing. Below are some strategiesthat <strong>the</strong> HPFP has learned to adopt throughyears of engagement with public and private agencies.Alignment with electoral cycles: One of <strong>the</strong> lessonsfrom previous engagement experiences is that anyprojects or concessions approved by elected officialsshould be completed within <strong>the</strong> electoralperiod. Thus, planning must also be aligned wi<strong>the</strong>lectoral cycles.Establishing relationships with career officials:Despite changes in elected officials, <strong>the</strong> HPFPcan maintain relationships with career officials,who retain <strong>the</strong>ir positions even after changes inpolitical leadership. The HPFP continues to receivesupport from career officials, some of whomendorse <strong>the</strong> officials.Show of numbers and a broad netw<strong>ork</strong>: The HPFPalso uses its national and international netw<strong>ork</strong> toobtain concessions from public agencies, and <strong>the</strong>rehave been instances where government officialsand landowners have agreed to certain concessionswhen <strong>the</strong>se were requested in <strong>the</strong> presenceof large numbers of people. The federation hasused its international connections and its membershipin international groups (<strong>for</strong> example, <strong>the</strong>Shack/Slum Dwellers International) to <strong>for</strong>ce closerrelationships with important public officials. It hasalso invited public officials to participate in multilateralprojects and international exchanges, thushelping to consolidate individual relationships andidentify win—win strategies.Capitalising on its track record and <strong>the</strong> HPFP nameto bolster local ef<strong>for</strong>ts: The HPFP has earned credibilitywith government and private organisationsthrough its self-help ef<strong>for</strong>ts in mobilising savingsand securing land tenure. Government functionariesand private agencies usually ignore HPFPcommunities until <strong>the</strong>y find out about <strong>the</strong> financialstake members have invested in <strong>the</strong>ir w<strong>ork</strong>, <strong>the</strong>gains <strong>the</strong>y have achieved through <strong>the</strong>ir own initiativeand <strong>the</strong> netw<strong>ork</strong>s that <strong>the</strong>y have been able toestablish.Streng<strong>the</strong>ning technical know-how. Needless to say,good technical know-how is critical to taking a principledand in<strong>for</strong>med position when negotiating. Unlesscommunity associations know how to express<strong>the</strong>ir interests in operational terms, <strong>the</strong>y will not be181


able to go beyond general statements of intent, andmay inevitably fall prey to unscrupulous parties whocan conceal <strong>the</strong>ir intent behind complex terminology,legalese, ma<strong>the</strong>matical <strong>for</strong>mulae and unverifieddocuments. Building technical skills is <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>ean important component of successful engagementwith <strong>the</strong> state. The HPFP makes it a point to sharein<strong>for</strong>mation and transfer <strong>the</strong>ir knowledge to a widerange of communities. 87Case 6:Legislative Initiatives <strong>for</strong> UnorganisedW<strong>ork</strong>ersTwo legal initiatives in India are described belowconcerning Unorganised W<strong>ork</strong>ers. 88Unorganised Sector W<strong>ork</strong>ers (Employment andWelfare) Bill, IndiaAt present, <strong>the</strong> Government of India is actively reviewinga national bill on w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> unorganisedsector, which was drafted by <strong>the</strong> National Commissionon Labour and submitted to Parliament in2002. This Bill has <strong>the</strong> objectives of regulating ‘<strong>the</strong>employment and conditions of service of unorganisedsector w<strong>ork</strong>ers and to provide <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir safety,social security, health and welfare.’ 89 It defines aw<strong>ork</strong>er as ‘a person engaged in Scheduled Employmentwhe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong> any remuneration or o<strong>the</strong>rwise.’(Some 122 occupations are listed as ScheduledEmployment.) The bill, fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, provides <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> establishment of W<strong>ork</strong>ers’ Facilitation Centresto support and assist unorganised w<strong>ork</strong>ers, who:1) are responsible <strong>for</strong> registration of w<strong>ork</strong>ers and<strong>for</strong> guidance on a range of issues, such as disputeresolution, self-help groups and schemes available<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir benefit; 2) will maintain a register of w<strong>ork</strong>ersand provide an identity card and social securitynumber and 3) will be responsible <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>mulatingsafety and social security schemes, includinghealth and medical care, employment injury benefit,maternity benefit, old age pension and safetymeasures.Additionally, <strong>the</strong> bill provides <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> setting up,at state level, of an Unorganised Sector W<strong>ork</strong>ers’Welfare Fund, supported with funds from government,employers and registered w<strong>ork</strong>ers. It alsosets out minimum conditions of service, includinghours of w<strong>ork</strong> and minimum wages.There is an attempt as well to safeguard <strong>the</strong> rightsof women. Wage discrimination on <strong>the</strong> grounds ofgender is prohibited and a female w<strong>ork</strong>er is entitledto ‘such maternity benefits with wages asprescribed.’ Employers are also liable to pay compensation<strong>for</strong> injury on duty. (Source: Governmentof India, 2003)Unorganised Sector W<strong>ork</strong>ers’ Social SecurityScheme, IndiaOver 90 percent of India’s w<strong>ork</strong>ers are in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy (including agricultural w<strong>ork</strong>ers),with little, if any, statutory social security. Most arecasual labourers, contract and piece-rate w<strong>ork</strong>ersand self-employed own-account w<strong>ork</strong>ers. The Governmentof India recently launched <strong>the</strong> UnorganisedSector W<strong>ork</strong>ers’ Social Security Scheme on apilot basis in 50 districts. The scheme provides <strong>for</strong>three basic protections: old age pension, personalaccident insurance, and medical insurance. It iscompulsory <strong>for</strong> registered employees and voluntary<strong>for</strong> self-employed w<strong>ork</strong>ers. W<strong>ork</strong>ers contribute to<strong>the</strong> scheme, as do employers. Where self-employedw<strong>ork</strong>ers join <strong>the</strong> scheme, <strong>the</strong>y pay w<strong>ork</strong>er and employercontributions. Government also contributes.W<strong>ork</strong>ers Facilitation Centres are being set up toassist w<strong>ork</strong>ers (see above under Securing Rightsof In<strong>for</strong>mal W<strong>ork</strong>ers). The scheme will be administeredthrough <strong>the</strong> already existing Employee ProvidentFund Organisation offices around <strong>the</strong> country(Source: Government of India, 2004).182


Case 7:Social security <strong>for</strong> all in <strong>the</strong>PhilippinesIn <strong>the</strong> Philippines, two complementary facilities -<strong>the</strong> statutory social security system and <strong>the</strong> healthinsurance scheme — are being made progressivelyaccessible to everyone through voluntary schemesthat are open to self-employed w<strong>ork</strong>ers, lowerpricedpackages and a wider netw<strong>ork</strong> of collectionunits, including banks and organised groups.The Philippines Social Security System (SSS) offersa comprehensive range of cash benefits asinsurance <strong>for</strong> retirement, death, disability, maternity,sickness, old age, death and w<strong>ork</strong>-relatedinjuries. In 1995, it extended membership to <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal sector under its self-employed and voluntarymembership scheme. Under this scheme,<strong>the</strong> minimum monthly salary to qualify as an SSSmember was lowered to P1,000 and <strong>the</strong> definitionof self-employed was expanded to ‘all selfemployedpersons regardless of trade, business oroccupation, with a monthly net income of at leastP1,000.’ This definition would include householdhelp, individual farmers, fisher folk and o<strong>the</strong>rsmall entrepreneurs who may join <strong>the</strong> scheme asvoluntary members. 90As of December 2002, SSS covered about 24.3million members, of whom 4.5 million are self-employedor w<strong>ork</strong>ing in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. However,<strong>the</strong> scheme continues to have problems withcompliance, and w<strong>ork</strong>ers often blame non-membershipon lack of time, lack of in<strong>for</strong>mation, lackof regular employment, cost of contributions, anddifficulties trying to contact SSS representatives.The Philippine Health Insurance Corporation (Phil-Health) used to be integrated with <strong>the</strong> Social SecuritySystem, but was separated, in part, to lower<strong>the</strong> cost of medical insurance package <strong>for</strong> householdsthat set <strong>the</strong>ir priorities <strong>for</strong> immediate ra<strong>the</strong>rthan <strong>the</strong> longer-term medical needs covered by<strong>the</strong> SSS. Phil-Health administers health insuranceand provides hospitalisation as well as out-patientbenefits to its members and <strong>the</strong>ir beneficiaries intimes of need and illness.Phil-Health has expanded its programme to includethose w<strong>ork</strong>ing in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy through <strong>the</strong>‘Individually Paying Programme’ (IPP). In 2002,Phil-Health covered 54.6 million Filipinos, or 64percent of <strong>the</strong> country’s projected population <strong>for</strong>December 2005. Of <strong>the</strong> total covered, 54 percentare employed; 15 percent are individual payers;sponsor 22 percent by third parties, and 0.6 arenon-paying members. Individual payers include<strong>the</strong> self-employed (market vendors, farmers, fisherfolk),private practitioners and professionals(doctors, lawyers), and those separated from w<strong>ork</strong>.With 2.9 million members as of March 2006, it iscalculated that IPP membership grows by an averageof 30 percent each year.Under <strong>the</strong> IPP, household heads pay a monthlycontribution of only P100 (currently just over $2)to have <strong>the</strong>ir families covered by health insurance.This entitles members and <strong>the</strong>ir dependentsto limited hospital coverage <strong>for</strong> room and board,laboratory tests, medicines and doctors’ fees whenconfined in a hospital. Phil-Health has fur<strong>the</strong>rpilot-tested a partnership with organised groupssuch as cooperatives to facilitate its reach to thosewho are difficult to reach individually.Lowering <strong>the</strong> cost of insurance packages, allowingmore frequent collection, and partnering withorganised groups, could serve to make such voluntaryschemes available to all.183


Case 8:Minimum Living Standard SecuritySystem in ChinaIn 1993, <strong>the</strong> Chinese government began to re<strong>for</strong>m<strong>the</strong> social relief system in cities, at <strong>the</strong> same timeseeking to try out a minimum living standard securitysystem. In 1999, this security system wasestablished in all cities and county towns throughout<strong>the</strong> country. In <strong>the</strong> same year, <strong>the</strong> Chinesegovernment officially promulgated <strong>the</strong> Regulationson Guaranteeing Urban Residents’ Minimum Standardof Living to ensure <strong>the</strong> basic livelihood of allurban residents. This has been decided ‘primarilyon <strong>the</strong> basis of urban residents’ average incomeand consumption level per capita, <strong>the</strong> price levelof <strong>the</strong> previous year, <strong>the</strong> consumption price index,<strong>the</strong> local cost necessary <strong>for</strong> maintaining <strong>the</strong> basiclivelihood, o<strong>the</strong>r connected social security standards,<strong>the</strong> materials <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> basic needs of food,clothing and housing, and <strong>the</strong> expenditure on under-agechildren’s compulsory education.’ 91Funds <strong>for</strong> this purpose are included in <strong>the</strong> fiscalbudgets of <strong>the</strong> local people’s governments, whichdetermine <strong>the</strong> minimum living standard accordingto <strong>the</strong> cost necessary <strong>for</strong> maintaining <strong>the</strong> basiclivelihood of <strong>the</strong> local urbanites. Urban residentswith an average family income lower than <strong>the</strong> minimumliving standard can apply <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> minimumliving allowance. Investigation of <strong>the</strong> family’s incomeshall be conducted be<strong>for</strong>e issuance of <strong>the</strong>minimum living allowance, <strong>the</strong> level of which iscalculated in terms of <strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong>family per-capita income and <strong>the</strong> minimum livingstandard.Case 9:Labour protection <strong>for</strong> subcontractsin ChileIn 2006, a law regulating subcontracting was introducedin Chile. According to <strong>the</strong> Ministry ofLabour, 35 percent of w<strong>ork</strong>ers in Chile are notdirectly hired by large firms finding w<strong>ork</strong> insteadthrough subcontractors or o<strong>the</strong>r providers of personnel.At present, responsibility <strong>for</strong> labour obligationsrests with <strong>the</strong> hiring firm. Compliance isoften low and capacity to pay limited, particularlyin <strong>the</strong> case of personnel suppliers who can operatewith little capital. In this way, labour obligationsare thoroughly diluted. The situation is such thatsome hiring firms are <strong>the</strong>mselves creations of <strong>the</strong>principal firms.The law introduced in Chile regulates both typesof arrangements, but <strong>the</strong> objective is to limit <strong>the</strong>supply of labour to only short-term replacementw<strong>ork</strong>ers. In <strong>the</strong> case of subcontracting, <strong>the</strong> objectiveis to promote it but to ensure compliance withall <strong>the</strong> labour obligations, as follows:• A deposit of a re-adjustable guarantee (nearlyUS$9000 at recent exchange rates) is required<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> providers of labour, and <strong>the</strong> deposit canbe used in cases of non-compliance and a timelimit of six months has been introduced <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>contracts.• In <strong>the</strong> case of subcontracting, provisions wereintroduced on responsibility <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> labour obligations,which affect both subcontractors and<strong>the</strong> main firms regarding responsibility <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>labour obligations. Direct responsibility lies with<strong>the</strong> subcontractors, but <strong>the</strong> main firms have <strong>the</strong>right to request from <strong>the</strong> subcontractor a certificateof compliance (issued by <strong>the</strong> labour inspectorateagency), and <strong>the</strong>y also have <strong>the</strong> right towithhold payments <strong>for</strong> subcontractors in cases ofobligations still pending. In fact, <strong>the</strong> law trans<strong>for</strong>ms<strong>the</strong> principal firm into an instrument of la-184


our inspection and sanction and it ensures thatcompliance will increase. 92Case 10:Spain: Flexibility at <strong>the</strong> margin 93In Spain, a two-tiered hierarchy of standards wasapplied to different categories of w<strong>ork</strong>ers — withflexibility allowed <strong>for</strong> new entrants and unemployedpersons (to encourage firms to hire <strong>the</strong>m) and acontinued level of protection kept <strong>for</strong> permanentw<strong>ork</strong>ers (to avoid threatening <strong>the</strong> entire w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>cewith job insecurity).High unemployment rates during <strong>the</strong> first half of<strong>the</strong> 1980s in Spain triggered <strong>the</strong> adoption measuresto regulate contracts of limited duration (orfixed term contracts) to ensure that <strong>the</strong>y met minimumstandards of employment contracts whileleaving employment protection legislation <strong>for</strong> permanentw<strong>ork</strong>ers untouched. These contracts havelower dismissal costs and offer social securityrebates <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> first two years of <strong>the</strong> contract. Itis applicable only to w<strong>ork</strong>ers below 30 years orover 45 years, long-term unemployed and disabledw<strong>ork</strong>ers.Overall, fixed-term contracts have been instrumentalin increasing employment in Spain while maintaininga certain degree of labour rights. This hasbenefited some specific groups of w<strong>ork</strong>ers, mainlylow skilled, and is clearly a better option than remainingunemployed. 94In 2006, Spanish trade unions, employers’ organisationsand government signed an agreement toprovide additional safeguards within <strong>the</strong>se contracts,and to bring contractual arrangements moreinto line with <strong>the</strong> European social model. The mainpoints of <strong>the</strong> agreement are as follows:• After more than 24 months on a fixed-termcontract in <strong>the</strong> same enterprise and doing <strong>the</strong>same job, over a reference period of 30 months,<strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>er’s contract becomes one of indefiniteduration;• Employer bonuses <strong>for</strong> four years when targetgroups (women, youngsters, and longer-term unemployed)are offered an open-ended contract;• Precise definition of and action against illegalposting of w<strong>ork</strong>ers between firms;• Cuts in employer social security contribution;• Extended unemployment benefits <strong>for</strong> olderw<strong>ork</strong>ers, and measures to increase protectionof flexible fixed-term w<strong>ork</strong>ers.The success of fixed-term contracts in Spain is stilla matter of discussion. Given <strong>the</strong> strict regulationson permanent employment, <strong>the</strong> main attractivenessof fixed term contracts is <strong>the</strong> flexibility andlow firing costs <strong>the</strong>y entail. This kind of contractsallows <strong>for</strong> a quick adaptation of <strong>the</strong> staff to changingeconomic conditions.An important element in <strong>the</strong> assessment of fixedtermcontracts is whe<strong>the</strong>r w<strong>ork</strong>ers with temporaryarrangements are trapped in this situation <strong>for</strong> along time or, on <strong>the</strong> contrary, can obtain a permanentjob after a relatively short period. It is saidthat fixed-term contracts could serve as screeningdevices that allow employers to observe w<strong>ork</strong>ers’per<strong>for</strong>mance. Skilful w<strong>ork</strong>ers would thus obtain apermanent contract after a probation period holdinga fixed-term contract. 95 However, this transitionfrom a temporary to a permanent post in Spain is,in general, ra<strong>the</strong>r slow and takes longer at presentthan in <strong>the</strong> past. 96The disadvantages of this measure must also benoted. There is, <strong>for</strong> example, little incentive as aresult ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong> employers or w<strong>ork</strong>ers to invest inhuman capital and reduced overall labour mobility,due to inherent uncertainty, lower remunerationand high housing costs.185


Case 11:China’s positive responses to growingmarket economySince <strong>the</strong> founding of <strong>the</strong> People’s Republicof China in 1949, a planned economic systemhas been adopted, whereby highly concentratedemployment and wage and labour systemsguaranteed <strong>the</strong> livelihood of employees, and alsopromoted social security.However, this system has had to adapt with <strong>the</strong>changes in economic and social development, particularlysince 1978, when China began its policyof re<strong>for</strong>m and opening up. This period was markedby a focus on economic construction that swiftlymoved towards what has been called a ‘socialistmarket economy system.’As a result, labour and social security structuresunderwent many changes. Most obviously, Chinaexperienced unprecedented economic growth ofbetween eight to 12 percent, far exceeding <strong>the</strong>centralised and collective growth patterns. This inturn affected employment patterns in cities withlarge urban migration from rural areas, un-contractedhires, long w<strong>ork</strong>ing hours, and low wages,with little or no job security or safety protection.Meanwhile, rural unemployment was also on <strong>the</strong>increase and <strong>the</strong> gulf between classes was widening.It is estimated that <strong>the</strong>re are more than 150million redundant rural labourers, with an unemploymentrate in urban areas and townships standingat over four percent.However, <strong>the</strong> most far reaching ef<strong>for</strong>ts to change<strong>the</strong> law were announced in March 2006 by PremierWen Jiabao in his annual speech at <strong>the</strong> NationalPeople’s Congress. The wide ranging economic re<strong>for</strong>mpackage includes a new labour law addressingw<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions in China. With some amendments,influenced to some extent by <strong>the</strong> ILO, <strong>the</strong>new labour ruling has become law taking effect 1January 2008. The State is now declared to haveobligations, good governance, better public institutions,protection clauses, contracts, regulationsand legal arbitrations. The re<strong>for</strong>m package indicatesthat <strong>the</strong> State will play a crucial role by rethinkingdevelopment strategies and having solidpolicies in place. The following features are <strong>the</strong>most important of <strong>the</strong> new labour initiatives:• Most industrial employees, including migrantw<strong>ork</strong>ers are covered;• Provisions are clarified <strong>for</strong> collective contractsthat apply to groups of w<strong>ork</strong>ers and employersindustry-wide or within a given region;• The employer must account <strong>for</strong> any deviationfrom <strong>the</strong> labour standards imposed by law,which also includes a requirement <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>m toprovide written contracts;• The courts will take a more stringent approachto labour violations as per <strong>the</strong> new laws. In fact,should <strong>the</strong> employer be found in violation ofei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> law or even ‘administrative regulations’,<strong>the</strong> labour administration has <strong>the</strong> powerto issue warnings or ‘rectifications’ dependingon <strong>the</strong> severity of <strong>the</strong> violation. There are alsoprovisions within <strong>the</strong> law <strong>for</strong> damages and evencriminal liability in those cases where labourrights are grossly infringed. The law strictlylimits tacking on probationary periods duringwhich <strong>the</strong> employer can arbitrarily terminate anemployee. This feature is designed to overcomean abusive practice that deprives employeesof protections from arbitrary discharge and requires‘just cause’ be<strong>for</strong>e an employee is dismissed;• This proposed law regulates <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> first time<strong>the</strong> new industry of labour brokers or ‘labourdispatchers,’ which has grown up to furnish exportindustries with ‘just-in-time’ w<strong>ork</strong>ers whohave dubious legal status as employees under186


<strong>the</strong> law and <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e are often unprotected;• If employers keep using a temporary employee<strong>for</strong> more than two fixed — term contracts, <strong>the</strong>contract has to be converted into an indefiniteterm contract, thus ending <strong>the</strong> practice of ‘casualising’employment;• This draft law regulates abuses of ‘non-compete’clauses, whereby employers saddle skilledw<strong>ork</strong>ers in IT and o<strong>the</strong>r sectors with excessiverestrictions on who <strong>the</strong>y can w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> in <strong>the</strong> futureand severely hamper future job mobilitywith legal entanglements.To correct a predisposition in Chinese courts andamong labour arbitrators to exalt <strong>for</strong>m over substanceand facts, <strong>the</strong> proposed changes make <strong>the</strong>facts and realities of <strong>the</strong> employment relationship<strong>the</strong> key. Employees would no longer be confrontedwith <strong>the</strong> dilemma of en<strong>for</strong>cing a contract where<strong>the</strong> employer has illegally withheld one.Case 12:Out-of-court dispute resolution as apractical tool <strong>for</strong> legal empowermentFor poor people around <strong>the</strong> world, getting accessto courts and legal support to protect <strong>the</strong>ir rightsis often impossible. In many cases, <strong>the</strong> reason <strong>for</strong>this is straight<strong>for</strong>ward — <strong>the</strong>y cannot af<strong>for</strong>d to pay<strong>the</strong> legal fees. In Tajikistan, <strong>the</strong> UK has helped tosolve this problem by supporting Third Party ArbitrationCourts. These courts are an alternative wayof resolving disputes: two sides of a dispute agreeto nominate a third party who <strong>the</strong>y both trust tomediate <strong>the</strong>ir disagreement and come to a decision.Although <strong>the</strong>y operate independently of <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mal legal system, decisions are recognised byTajikistan’s official courts. This means that whereparties do not comply with a decision, <strong>the</strong> statecan step in to en<strong>for</strong>ce it.Third Party Arbitration Courts provide poor peoplewith a cheap, fair and accessible way of resolvingdisputes and protecting <strong>the</strong>ir rights. They areparticularly effective at protecting <strong>the</strong> rights ofwomen to land and property.Third Party Arbitration has helped to make legalservices available to 800,000 people in Tajikistan(12 percent of <strong>the</strong> population). The approach hasalso been used successfully in Russia, Kyrgyzstan,Moldova, Ukraine and Georgia. 100Case 13:Revising bidding and procurementpractices in SenegalGovernment can have a direct role to play in expandingopportunities <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sectorthrough affirmative action to purchase <strong>the</strong> goodsand services of <strong>the</strong> sector. In view of <strong>the</strong> weaknessesof <strong>the</strong> sector, government must changecontracting procedures, reduce barriers and makegovernment purchases more accessible to <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal sector. There should also be improvedchannels of in<strong>for</strong>mation between government and<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector so that <strong>the</strong> government wouldknow what products are available while those in<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal scetor would know what governmentis buying. With regard to simplifying requirements,<strong>the</strong> following actions are proposed:• Break large requirements into smaller sizes thatare more manageable by small suppliers.• Simplify bidding procedures <strong>for</strong> smaller requirements.• Reassess existing regulations with a viewto giving priority to internal sourcingof products.• Reassess procedures with a view to ensuringthat payments are made promptly to <strong>the</strong> suppli-187


er, perhaps even prepaid, to ease <strong>the</strong> financialrequirements of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector suppliers.• Establish effective control systems to ensurethat <strong>the</strong>se affirmative actions do not compromise<strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> a reasonable price, goodquality and timeliness. 101The Senegalese Government provides an exampleof a proactive policy of contracting out public infrastructureprojects to small scale contractors. Biddingprocedures and documents have been substantiallysimplified to permit smaller contractorsto participate in <strong>the</strong> bidding process. Bureaucraticdocumentation was also minimised while biddingdocuments now contain official unit cost estimatesas a guide to <strong>the</strong> less sophisticated contractor. Ageneral session is held wherein contractors are in<strong>for</strong>medabout <strong>the</strong> existence of <strong>the</strong> implementingagency and are apprised of <strong>the</strong> entire procedure,from <strong>the</strong> bidding to <strong>the</strong> awarding and implementation.Simplification of <strong>the</strong> process goes as far asmaking <strong>the</strong> name of <strong>the</strong> winner very clear in <strong>the</strong>announcement, so that even an illiterate contractor’srepresentative can readily determine who wasawarded <strong>the</strong> contract.The contract that <strong>the</strong> successful bidder has to signis basic and contains only essential elements, withsuperfluous or general content removed. The modelcontract used <strong>for</strong> all such projects is written inlanguage that is understandable to <strong>the</strong> layperson,avoiding legal jargon and complicated terminology.During <strong>the</strong> implementation of <strong>the</strong> contract, technicalassistance is provided to <strong>the</strong> awarded contractorregarding productivity improvement and basicmanagement. The technical assistance programmecomprises <strong>the</strong> following components: 1) short courseson basic management covering recordkeeping,accounting, stock control, and sub-project management;2) short courses and on-site technical assis-188tance <strong>for</strong> contractors’ managers, site supervisorsand <strong>for</strong>emen to improve technical management of<strong>the</strong> construction jobs to improve productivity; and3) ad hoc training <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>emen and constructionw<strong>ork</strong>ers on specific construction techniques relatedto <strong>the</strong> job on hand. By its second year of operationin 1992, <strong>the</strong> programme had reached approximately720 individuals representing over 500 firms. 12


Chapter 3 Endnotes1 See Resolution concerning <strong>the</strong> promotion of sustainableenterprises, International Labour Conference, June 2007.2 World Bank, 2002a.3 Anne Trebilcock, 2005.4 Loayza, 2007.5 Declaration on Fundamental Principles and Rights at W<strong>ork</strong>, ILO,1998.6 ‘Decent W<strong>ork</strong> and <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy,’ Report of <strong>the</strong> Director-General, International Labour Conference, ILO, Geneva, 2002.7 In 2003, <strong>the</strong> International Conference of Labour Statisticiansendorsed a statistical framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> measuring in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.8 Alsop and Heinsohn, 2005.9 World Bank 2002b.10 Trebilcock, A., 2006.11 ILO, 1999.12 Loayza and Rigolini ,2006.13 ILO, 2002b.14 Heintz and Pollin, 2003.15 This summary is based on recent analyses of available nationaldata (using <strong>the</strong> indirect measure of estimating in<strong>for</strong>mal employmentas <strong>the</strong> difference between total employment [estimated by labour <strong>for</strong>cesurveys or population censuses] and <strong>for</strong>mal employment [estimatedby enterprise surveys or economic censuses]) as well as earliersummaries of <strong>the</strong>se analyses in Chen et al 2005. The authors of ILO2002 as well as Heintz and Pollin (2003) analysed a common set ofoffi cial national data collected and compiled by Jacques Charmes.16 National labour <strong>for</strong>ce data do not capture all <strong>for</strong>ms of in<strong>for</strong>malemployment <strong>for</strong> a variety of reasons. One reason is that some lawfulpaid activities are not declared to public authorities. The extent andcharacteristics of lawful but undeclared w<strong>ork</strong> differ widely betweencountries. A 2004 study <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> European Commission found thatundeclared w<strong>ork</strong> represented as much as 20 percent of GDP in somesou<strong>the</strong>rn and eastern European countries (‘Undeclared W<strong>ork</strong> in anEnlarged Union’ 2004.) Of course, criminal activities are also notdeclared to public authorities. But <strong>the</strong> defi nition of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy used by <strong>the</strong> Commission and in this Report excludes criminalactivities.17 See, Hu, A., The Emergence of In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector and <strong>the</strong>Development of In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy in China’s Transition: A HistoricalPerspective (1952-2004) —(pdf version, slide 4) Available: http://ccs.tinghua.edu.cn and http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTDECABCTOK2006/Resources/H_Angang.ppt18 In<strong>for</strong>mal wage employment is comprised of employees ofin<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises as well as various types of in<strong>for</strong>mal wage w<strong>ork</strong>erswho w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal enterprises, households, or no fi xed employer.These include casual day labourers, domestic w<strong>ork</strong>ers, industrialoutw<strong>ork</strong>ers (notably homew<strong>ork</strong>ers), undeclared w<strong>ork</strong>ers, and part-timeor temporary w<strong>ork</strong>ers without secure contracts, w<strong>ork</strong>er benefi ts, orsocial protection.19 Chen et al., 2005.20 Analysis of national data by Jacques Charmes, cited in Chen etal., 2005.21 These fi gures were computed by Jeemol Unni using <strong>the</strong> individualrecords of <strong>the</strong> Employment and Unemployment Survey, 1999-2000,55th Round of <strong>the</strong> National Sample Survey Organisation, New Delhi.22 Heintz ,2006.23 Loayza and Rigolini, 2006. For fi gures on China, also see Hu,Angang, The Emergence of In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector and <strong>the</strong> Developmentof In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy in China’s Transition: A Historical Perspective(1952-2004). Available: http://ccs.tinghua.edu.cnand at: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTDECABCTOK2006/Resources/H_Angang.ppt24 Chen et al. 2005.25 Heintz 2006. Blunch et al. 2001.26 Statisticians distinguish three main sub-categories of selfemployment:1) ‘employers’, <strong>the</strong> self-employed who hire o<strong>the</strong>rs; 2)‘own account w<strong>ork</strong>ers’, who do not hire o<strong>the</strong>rs; 2’; and 3) ‘unpaidcontributing family w<strong>ork</strong>ers’. However, many statistical analyses,such as those by <strong>the</strong> OECD reported by Carré 2006, exclude unpaidfamily members because <strong>the</strong>y are considered ‘assistants’, not‘entrepreneurs’. Since <strong>the</strong> majority of unpaid family w<strong>ork</strong>ers in mostcontexts are women, this exclusion understates <strong>the</strong> real level ofwomen’s labour <strong>for</strong>ce participation and entrepreneurship (Carré 2006).27 UNRISD 2005, Heintz 200528 Heintz 2005.29 ibid.30 Chen et al 2005.31 Carré 2006:1332 Ibid.33 Tomei 2005.34 ILO 2003b.35 Based on conception provided by <strong>the</strong> United Nations Rapporteur,Martinez-Cobo, in <strong>the</strong> Study on <strong>the</strong> Problem of Discrimination againstIndigenous Populations. Cited in Tomei 2005.36 Tomei, 2005.37 ibid.38 Chen 2006b.39 Article I of <strong>the</strong> Declaration of Philadelphia, International LabourConference, 1944, Annex to <strong>the</strong> Constitution of <strong>the</strong> International LabourOrganisation.40 ILO 2006.41 Although a number of ILO labour standards addressed w<strong>ork</strong>ersoutside of <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy (e.g., indigenous and tribal peoples,rural w<strong>ork</strong>ers, etc.) since <strong>the</strong> 1960s, <strong>the</strong>se did not previously result ininternational policy conclusions on <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malisation as a growingglobal trend.42 Stiglitz 2001.43 ILO 2002b.44 Freeman 1996.45 Tokman 2007a.46 Anne Trebilcock 2004.47 Paragraph 47 of <strong>the</strong> 2005 Summit Outcome Document.189


48 Including <strong>the</strong> UN funds, programmes and agencies, regionaleconomic commissions and development banks, as well as <strong>the</strong>international fi nancial institutions and <strong>the</strong> World Trade Organisation(WTO)49 Summit Outcome Document, ECOSOC 2006 Declaration.50 See Marty Chen, ‘Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor: Process andOutcomes’, Harvard, July 20, 2007.5152 This could be guided by <strong>the</strong> Employment RelationshipRecommendations, 2006, adopted by <strong>the</strong> 91st session of <strong>the</strong>International Labour Conference.53 Chile adopted a new law in 2006 to regulate <strong>the</strong>searrangements, allocating solidarity responsibilities to sub-contractorand subcontracting fi rms involved. It also introduced <strong>the</strong> right of<strong>the</strong> latter to control <strong>the</strong> compliance of <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mer and to convert itsresponsibility into subsidiary. It also adapted <strong>the</strong> Labour Inspection tobe able to certify <strong>the</strong> degree of en<strong>for</strong>cement on line and up dated.54 See V. Tokman, “In<strong>for</strong>mality, insecurity and social cohesion inLatin America’, International Labour Review, vol. 126 (2007), number1-2, ILO, Geneva. In Bogota, Colombia a survey of micro enterprisesindicates that 76 percent among <strong>the</strong>m could not pay all <strong>the</strong> labourcontributions required by law, and in Lima, Peru this percentagereached to 85 percent.55 ILO, ‘Business environment, labour law and micro and smallenterprises’, Committee on Employment and Social Policy, GoverningBody 297th session, Geneva, 2006. Ano<strong>the</strong>r specifi c experience is <strong>the</strong>change of pecuniary sanctions by using <strong>the</strong> resources <strong>for</strong> improving<strong>the</strong> knowledge of micro-entrepreneurs on <strong>the</strong>ir obligations in Chile.Although ignorance cannot be claimed as an excuse <strong>for</strong> lack ofcompliance, <strong>the</strong>re is need <strong>for</strong> support when levels of education are lowand access to costly professional services cannot be af<strong>for</strong>ded.56 See Resolution concerning <strong>the</strong> promotion of sustainableenterprises, 96th Session of <strong>the</strong> International Labour Conference, June2007.57 See Case 6, annexed to this chapter.58 See Case 7.59 World Bank, ‘In<strong>for</strong>mality: Exit and Exclusion’, Washington , 2007.60 The public funds involved are <strong>the</strong> highest in Bolivia (1,2percentof GNP) and are estimated <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> quasi-universal pension of Chile at1,0 percent compared to <strong>the</strong> focused pensions in <strong>the</strong> Region that areusually below 0,5 percent of GNP.61 See International Labour Conference, Resolution on <strong>the</strong>employment relationship, Geneva, 2006.62 The current, dominant rubric <strong>for</strong> understanding and analysing<strong>the</strong> impact of regulation on economic growth is through <strong>the</strong> use ofmulti-country surveys, whose core function is to provide measuresof <strong>the</strong> costs of business regulation within an economy. These multicountrysurveys have, over a fairly short space of time, come todominate global, regional and country-level policy discussions around<strong>the</strong> potential economic consequences of labour market regulation.Two of <strong>the</strong>se surveys loom large <strong>for</strong> analytical w<strong>ork</strong> on <strong>the</strong> developingworld, namely <strong>the</strong> Investment Climate Assessment (ICA) surveys and<strong>the</strong> Doing Business Survey (DBS) — both run under <strong>the</strong> auspices of<strong>the</strong> World Bank. The ICA measures fi rms’ perceptions of <strong>the</strong> investmentclimate in <strong>the</strong>ir country and are based on a standard core module(See http://rru.worldbank.org/InvestmentClimate/About.aspx <strong>for</strong> thisstandard questionnaire). The questionnaire covers senior manager’sperceptions of obstacles to growth and investment, as well asin<strong>for</strong>mation on fi rm per<strong>for</strong>mance. The data is organised accordingto a series of topics including infrastructure and services; fi nance;government policies and services; labour relations and innovation(World Bank, 2007). Currently <strong>the</strong> ICA includes data on 58 countries(World Bank, 2007). The Doing Business Survey (DBS) has beenongoing since 2004, and in <strong>the</strong> most recent round in 2007, coveredclose to 180 countries. The DBS deals with issues such as contracten<strong>for</strong>cement; property rights regulation; business licensing and ofparticular interest to us here — labour market regulation. The methodof data collection is a combination of studying individual country lawsand regulations and surveys of local lawyers.63 For fur<strong>the</strong>r background on <strong>the</strong>se questions, see Berg and Kucera(eds.), In Defence of Labour Market Institutions: Cultivating Justice in<strong>the</strong> Developing World (<strong>for</strong>thcoming).64 Botero et al (2004) undertook a seminal study on <strong>the</strong> impact oflabour regulation around <strong>the</strong> world. The data covers 85 countries andis very deliberate in its construction of indices of labour regulationranging from, <strong>for</strong> example, laws on overtime and part-time w<strong>ork</strong> tothose on dismissals, notice periods and <strong>the</strong> right to strike activity andcollective bargaining. The in<strong>for</strong>mation is representative of countrylevelin<strong>for</strong>mation <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> late 1990s, and in most cases refl ects data<strong>for</strong> 1997. It was, as far is known, <strong>the</strong> fi rst exhaustive, comprehensivemeasure of labour regulation that is cross-country in nature and notperception-based.65 Botero et al (2004), p. 1364, shows that of all <strong>the</strong> labourregulation measures, only dismissal procedures in <strong>the</strong>ir cross-countryregressions are a signifi cant and negative determinant of <strong>the</strong> logof GNP per capita, while social security provisions are positivelyassociated with growth.66 ILO Governing Body ‘The United Nations and Re<strong>for</strong>m’ 300thSession Geneva, November 2007 GB.300/4/167 Maloney 2003.68 McKinesey Quarterly, ‘The hidden dangers of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy.’69 IOE 2006.70 OECD 2006.71 Nickell and Layard 1998; and Levine and Tyson 1990.72 Gregg and Manning 1997.73 Saavedra and Torero 2004.74 Kugler et al. 2003.75 Acemoglu and Angrist 200176 In <strong>the</strong> case of Sara, et al., vs. Agarrado, et al. G.R. No. 73199, 26October 1988.77 See ILO,’The in<strong>for</strong>mal economy: enabling transition to<strong>for</strong>malisation,’ Tripartite Interregional Symposium on <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>malEconomy, Geneva, November 2007.78 See also Convention 156, W<strong>ork</strong>ers with Family Responsibilities.79 No. 177, 1966.80 See Annex 1 <strong>for</strong> more details.81 See Resolution concerning <strong>the</strong> promotion of sustainableenterprises, International Labour Conference, June 2007.82 Thanachaisethavut and Charoenlert 2006.190


83 Boundary: a cab driver, <strong>for</strong> example, pays a fi xed amount to <strong>the</strong>owner <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> use of <strong>the</strong> vehicle, retaining <strong>the</strong> fares above this amount<strong>for</strong> his expenses and keeping <strong>the</strong> balance as his actual earnings.84 In <strong>the</strong> case of Sara, et al., vs. Agarrado, et al. G.R. No. 73199, 26October 1988.85 Chen 2006c.86 As in o<strong>the</strong>r minimum wage negotiations, SEWA seeks to have<strong>the</strong> minimum wage fi xed in a tripartite negotiation with <strong>the</strong> LabourCommissioner’s Offi ce, <strong>the</strong> employer, and <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ers so it will beacceptable to all concerned. Also, SEWA does not expect that <strong>the</strong>minimum wage will be en<strong>for</strong>ced but uses it as a benchmark or targetin on-going negotiations.87 Yu, S. and Karaos, A. 2004; UN-Habitat 2006.88 Chen 2006d.89 As noted earlier, ‘unorganised w<strong>ork</strong>er’ is <strong>the</strong> term used in India<strong>for</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ers in in<strong>for</strong>mal employment and does not imply that suchw<strong>ork</strong>ers are not organised into unions or o<strong>the</strong>r organisations90 Previously, <strong>the</strong> defi nition of <strong>the</strong> regular self-employed waslimited only to ‘all self-employed professionals, partners and singleproprietors of businesses, actors and actresses, directors, scriptwritersand news correspondents, who do not fall within <strong>the</strong> defi nition of <strong>the</strong>term ‘employee,’ professional athletes, coaches, trainers and jockeys’(Section 9-A, Social Security Act of 1997). Under <strong>the</strong> new resolution,<strong>the</strong> defi nition of self-employed has now been expanded to include lowincome earners.91 Government White Paper, 2004 at: http://www.china.org.cn/e-white/20040907/8.htm92 Tokman 2006.93 Larsson 2006.94 Estrada, and Izquierdo 2002.95 Guell-Rotllan and Petrongolo 2000.96 Dorantes, 2000.97 ‘China to train 60 million rural labourers be<strong>for</strong>e 2010’ in People’sDaily at : http//english.peopledaily.com.cn/200309/27/eng20030927_125088.shtml98 Wen Jiabao, Report of <strong>the</strong> W<strong>ork</strong> of <strong>the</strong> Government. Delivered at<strong>the</strong> Fourth Session of <strong>the</strong> Tenth National People’s Congress. 5 March2006. Available: http://big5.xinhuanet.com/gate/big5/news.xinhuanet.com/english/2006-03/14/content_4303943.htm99 ibid.100 DFID, 2006.101 Grierson and Mead 1995.102 Pean and Watson 1993.Chapter 3 BibliographyAcemoglu, D and J Angrist (2001) ‘Consequences of EmploymentProtection: The Case of <strong>the</strong> Americans with Disability Act’Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 109, October 2001.Ahmed, S and S.Devarajan (2007) Labour <strong>Law</strong>s: To Create Good Jobs,Re<strong>for</strong>m Labour Regulations.Oped. Special to The Economic Times, India.Ahsan, A. and C. Pagés (2007) Are all Labour Regulations Equal?Assessing <strong>the</strong> Effects of Job Security. Labour Dispute andContract Labour <strong>Law</strong>s in India. SP Discussion Paper No.0713. Social Protection Discussion Papers. World Bank:Washington.R. Alsop and Heinsohn, 2005. Measuring Empowerment in Practice:Structuring Analysis and Framing Indicators. World BankPolicy Research W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper No. 3510. Washington, DC,World Bank, Feb.Amuedo-Dorantes, C., 2000. ‘W<strong>ork</strong> transitions into and out ofinvoluntary temporary employment in a segmented market:evidence from Spain.’ Industrial and Labour RelationsReview, Vol. 53, Issue 2. pp. 309-325.Barrientos, A., D. Hulme and A. Shepherd. 2004. ‘Can Social ProtectionTackle Chronic Poverty?’ Background paper <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>Conference ‘Social Protection <strong>for</strong> Chronic Poverty - Risk,Needs and Rights — Protecting What? How?’ IDPM/University of Manchester, 23-24 February 2005.Besley,T. and R.Burgess. 2004. ‘Can Labour Regulations HinderEconomic Per<strong>for</strong>mance? Evidence from India.’ QuarterlyJournal of Economics. February. 91-134.Bhorat, Haroon. 2007. ‘Debates on Labour Regulations as a Cost ofDoing Business.’ Paper prepared <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> UN Commissionon Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor.Blunch, Niels-Hugo, Sudharshan Canagarajah, and Dhushyanth Raju.2001. ‘The In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector Revisited: A Syn<strong>the</strong>sis AcrossSpace and Time.’ Social Protection Discussion Paper No.0119. Washington, D.C. The World Bank, July.Botero, J.C., S.Djankov, R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes and A. Shleifer.2004. ‘The Regulation of Labour.’ Quarterly Journal ofEconomics. November. 1339-1382.Carré, Françoise and Joaquin Herranz, Jr. 2002. ‘In<strong>for</strong>mal Jobs inIndustrialized ‘North’ Countries.’ Background paper <strong>for</strong>Women and Men in In<strong>for</strong>mal Employment: A StatisticalPicture.Charmes, J. 2000. ‘The Contribution of In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector to GDP inDeveloping Countries: Assessment, Estimates, Methods,Orientations <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Future.’ Paper presented at <strong>the</strong> FourthMeeting of <strong>the</strong> Expert Group on In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector Statistics(Delhi Group), Geneva, 28-30 August 2000.Chen, M. 2007. ‘Institutional Mismatch: Formal Institutions andIn<strong>for</strong>mal Realities.’ Paper prepared <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> United NationsCommission of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. May 19._______. 2006a. ‘In<strong>for</strong>malisation of Labour Markets : Is Formalization<strong>the</strong> Answer ?’ Paper prepared <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> United NationsCommission of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor, November._______. 2006b. ‘Rethinking <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy: Linkages with191


<strong>the</strong> Formal Economy and In<strong>for</strong>mal Regulatory Environment.’In B. Guha-Khasnobis, R. Kanbur, E. Ostrom (ed.), Linking<strong>the</strong> Formal and In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy: Concepts and Measures.Ox<strong>for</strong>d: Ox<strong>for</strong>d University Press._______. 2006c. ‘Empowerment of In<strong>for</strong>mal W<strong>ork</strong>ers: Legal andO<strong>the</strong>r Interventions.’ Paper prepared <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> United NationsCommission of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. 15December._______. 2006d. ‘Empowerment of In<strong>for</strong>mal W<strong>ork</strong>ers: Legal andO<strong>the</strong>r Interventions.’ Paper prepared <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> United NationsCommission of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. 16December.Chen, M., J. Vanek, F. Lund, J. Heintz, R. Jhabvala and C. Bonner. 2005.Progress of <strong>the</strong> World’s Women 2005: Women, W<strong>ork</strong>, andPoverty. New Y<strong>ork</strong>: UNIFEM.Coase, R.H. 1937. ‘The nature of <strong>the</strong> fi rm.’ Economica (NS), 4: 386-405. As cited in Deakin 2004.Cooney, Sean, Tim Lindsey, Richard Mitchell and Zhu, Ying. 2002. <strong>Law</strong>and Labour Market Regulation in South East Asia. London:Routledge.Deakin, Simon. 2004. ‘Renewing labour market institutions.’ ILO SocialPolicy Lectures. Geneva: International Institute <strong>for</strong> LabourStudies.Department <strong>for</strong> International Development (DFID). 2006. ‘EliminatingWorld Poverty: <strong>Making</strong> governance w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor.’ Awhite paper on international development. Presented toParliament by <strong>the</strong> Secretary <strong>for</strong> International Development._______. 2004. ‘Labour Standards and Poverty Reduction.’Deyo, F.C.1989. Beneath <strong>the</strong> Miracle: Labour Subordination in <strong>the</strong> NewAsian Industrialism. Berkeley: University of Cali<strong>for</strong>niaPress.Dolado, J.J., et al. (1999), ‘Los problemas del mercado de trabajoen España: Empleo, <strong>for</strong>mación y salarios mínimos.’Ekonomiaz, Vol. 43.Dolado, J., F. Kramarz, S. Machin, A. Manning, D. Margolis, and C.Teulings. 1998. ‘The Economic Impact of Minimum Wagesin Europe.’ Economic Policy 23: 319-372.Dolado, J. J., C. García-Serrano, and J.F. Jimeno. 2002. ‘DrawingLessons from <strong>the</strong> Boom of Temporary Jobs in Spain.’ TheEconomic Journal, Vol. 112, F270-F295.Elliot, K.A., and R. Freeman. 2003. ‘Can labour standards improveunder globalization?’ Institute <strong>for</strong> International Economics,Washington DC.Estrada, A., P. Garcia-Perea and M. Izquierdo. 2002. ‘Los fl ujos detrabajadores en Espana: el impacto del empleo temporal.’Documento de Trabajo 02026, Banco de Espana.Forteza, Alvaro and Martín Rama. 2001, ‘Labour Market Rigidity and<strong>the</strong> Success of Economic Re<strong>for</strong>ms across more than 100Countries.’ mimeo. The World Bank: Washington DC.Freeman, Richard. 1996. ‘International labour standards and worldtrade: Friends or foes?’ In: Schott, Jeffrey J. (ed.), The WorldTrading System: Challenges Ahead. Washington: Institute<strong>for</strong> International Economics.Galli, Rossana and David Kucera. 2004. ‘Labour Standards andIn<strong>for</strong>mal Employment in Latin America.’ World DevelopmentVol. 32. (5)Gregg, P., and A. Manning. 1997. ‘Labour Market Regulation andUnemployment.’ In Snower, D. and de la Dehesa, G. (eds.),Unemployment Policy: Government Options <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> LabourMarket. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Grierson, John, and Donald Mead. 1995. ‘Business Linkages inZimbabwe: Concept, Practice and Strategies.’ GEMINIW<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper No. 50. PACT Publications, USA.Guell-Rotllan, G., and B. Petrongolo. 2000. ‘W<strong>ork</strong>ers’ transition fromtemporary to permanent employment: The Spanish case.’Centre <strong>for</strong> Economic Per<strong>for</strong>mance, London School ofEconomics and Political Science, Discussion paper 438.Heckman, J and C. Pagés. 2003. ‘<strong>Law</strong> and Employment: Lessons fromLatin America and <strong>the</strong> Caribbean.’ NBER W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper10129 . www.nber.org/papers/w10129Heintz, J. 2006. ‘Growth, Employment, and Poverty Reduction.’Discussion paper prepared <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>shop ‘Growth,Employment, and Poverty Reduction,’ held at <strong>the</strong>Department <strong>for</strong> International Development, 17 March 2006._______. 2005. ‘The Growing In<strong>for</strong>mality of Labour Markets.’ Paperpresented at <strong>the</strong> UNRISD/CGGS Conference on Gender andSocial Policy, Marstrand, Sweden, 28-29 May._______, and Robert Pollin. 2003. ‘In<strong>for</strong>malisation, economic growth,and <strong>the</strong> challenge of creating viable labour standards indeveloping countries.’ PERI W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper, No. 60, Amherst,MA: Political Economy Research Institute.Heintz, J. 2002. ‘Global Labour Standards: <strong>the</strong>ir impact andimplementation.’ PERI W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper 46. MA: University ofMassachusetts Amherst.McKinsey. 2004. ‘The Hidden Dangers of <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy.’McKinsey Quarterly, (3).Hudson, Ken. 1999. ‘No shortage of ‘nonstandard’ jobs.’ EconomicPolicy Institute Briefi ng Paper. Washington, D.C.Hussmanns, Ralf. 2004. ‘Defi ning and measuring in<strong>for</strong>malemployment.’ Geneva, International Labour Offi ce.International Labour Organisation (ILO). 2007. ‘The United Nationsand Re<strong>for</strong>m’ ILO Governing Body, 300 th Session, GB.300/4/1Geneva, November 2007_______. 2007. ‘Global Employment Trends 2007: Brief January2007.’_______. 2006. ‘In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy, Poverty and Employment: GoodPractices and Lessons Learned.’ Bangkok: ILO SubregionalOffi ce <strong>for</strong> East Asia, 2006_______. 2005. ‘World Employment Report 2004-05: EmploymentProductivity and Poverty Reduction.’ Geneva: InternationalLabour Organisation._______. 2003a. ‘W<strong>ork</strong>ing out of Poverty.’ Report of <strong>the</strong> Director-General. International Labour Conference 91 st Session2003. Geneva: International Labour Offi ce._______. 2003b. ‘ILO Convention on Indigenous and Tribal Peoples,1989.’ (No. 169): A Manual. Geneva: International LabourOffi ce._______. 2003c. ‘The Employment Relationship: An annotated guideto ILO Recommendation No. 198.’ Geneva: InternationalLabour Offi ce.192


_______. 2002a. ‘Decent W<strong>ork</strong> and <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy.’ Report of<strong>the</strong> Director-General, International Labour Conference, ILO,Geneva, 2002._______. 2002b. ‘Women and Men in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy : AStatistical Picture.’ Geneva: International Labour Offi ce._______. 1999. Decent W<strong>ork</strong>. Report of <strong>the</strong> Director General to <strong>the</strong>87 th Session of <strong>the</strong> International Labour Conference.Geneva: International Labour Offi ce.Kucera, David. 2004. ‘Core Labour Standards and EconomicDevelopment,’ Labour History, Vol. 45 (4)_______. 2001. ‘The effects of core w<strong>ork</strong>ers rights on labour costsand <strong>for</strong>eign direct investment: evaluating <strong>the</strong> ‘conventionalwisdom.’ ‘ Decent W<strong>ork</strong> Research Program DiscussionPaper, No. 130, International Institute <strong>for</strong> Labour Studies,Geneva.International Organisation of Employers (IOE). 2006. ‘The In<strong>for</strong>malEconomy — The Employers’ Approach.’ November.Jonge, Alice de. 2004. ‘Global Economic Forces and Individual LabourRights: An Uneasy Coexistence.’ Human Rights and HumanWelfare. Volume 4 (1) University of Denver.Kugler, A., J. F. Jimeno, and V. Hernanz. 2003. ‘EmploymentConsequences of Restrictive Permanent Contracts:Evidence from Spanish Labour Market Re<strong>for</strong>ms.’ CEPRDiscussion Papers 3724.Kuruvilla 1995 in Cooney. (fi nd publication info)Lazear, E. 1990. ‘Job Security Provisions and Employment.’ QuarterlyJournal of Economics. August. 699-726.Larsson, Allan. 2006. ‘Flexibility at <strong>the</strong> margin: Re<strong>for</strong>m of <strong>the</strong> labourmarket in Spain .’ Paper prepared <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> United NationsCommission of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor.Lecuyer, Normand and Jean Courdouan, eds. 2002. ‘New <strong>for</strong>ms oflabour administration: Actors in development.’ Geneva:International Labour Offi ce.Levine, D.I.,. and L.D.A. Tyson. 1990. ‘Participation, Productivity and<strong>the</strong> Firm’s Environment.’ In Blinder, A. (ed.). Paying <strong>for</strong>Productivity. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Lim, Lim. 2003. ‘Highlights of <strong>the</strong> ILC Conclusions.’ Presented at <strong>the</strong>Turin W<strong>ork</strong>shop on <strong>the</strong> Follow-up to <strong>the</strong> ILC Conclusions onDecent W<strong>ork</strong> and <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy, ILO InternationalTraining Centre, Turin, 10-12 Feb.Loayza,N., A.M.Oviedo and L.Serven. (2005) ‘The impact of Regulationon Growth and <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector: Cross CountryEvidence.’ Unpublished mimeo. World Bank: WashingtonDC.Loayza, N., A..M.Oviedo and L.Serven. 2007. The impact of regulationon growth and in<strong>for</strong>mality: cross-country evidence. Ox<strong>for</strong>dUniversity Press.Loayza, N. and J. Rigolini. 2006. ‘In<strong>for</strong>mality Trends and Cycles.’ WorldBank Policy Research W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper Series 4078, The WorldBank.Maloney, William. 2003. ‘In<strong>for</strong>mality revisited.’ World Bank PolicyResearch W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper Series 2965, The World Bank.Manning, Chris. 2004. ‘Legislating <strong>for</strong> Labour Protection : Bettingon <strong>the</strong> Weak or <strong>the</strong> Strong?’ W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper 2004/08. TheAustralian National University, Division of Economics,December.Marsden, D. 1999a. ‘Breaking <strong>the</strong> link. Has <strong>the</strong> employment contracthad its day?’ Centrepiece, 1999, winter, 20-23. As cited inDeakin 2004.Montenegro, C. and C. Pagés. 2003. ‘Who Benefi ts from Labour MarketRegulations? Chile 1960-1998.’ NBER W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper 9850.Morin, Marie-Laure. 2005. ‘Labour law and new <strong>for</strong>ms of corporateorganisation.’ International Labour Review, Volume 144, (1)Geneva: International Labour Offi ce.Murthi, Mamta, Michael J. Orszag, and Peter R. Orszag. 1999. ‘Thecharge ratio on individual accounts: Lessons from <strong>the</strong> U.K.experience.’ Birbeck College W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper 99-2. London,University of London, March.Narayan, D., R. Patel, K. Schaftt, A. Rademacher, and S. Koch-Schulte.1999. Can anyone hear us? Washington, DC, World Bank.National Statistics Offi ce. 1995. ‘1995 Urban In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector Survey inMetro Manila: Highlights of Findings.’ National StatisticsOffi ce.National Economic Development and Labour Council (NEDLAC) 2006.‘Impact of Labour Market Policy on <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy:Analysis and Recommendations.’ A NEDLAC CommunityConstituency Paper. 26 June.Nickell, S. and R. Layard. 1998. ‘Labour Market Institutions andEconomic Per<strong>for</strong>mance.’ In Ashenfelter, O. and Card, D.(eds.) Handbook of Labour Economics, Vol. 3C. Amsterdam:North Holland.North, Douglass. 1989. ‘Institutions and economic growth: Anhistorical introduction.’ World Development Vol. 17 (9):1319-1332.Organisation <strong>for</strong> Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).2006. ‘OECD Employment Outlook,’ www.oecd.org.____. 2000. International Trade and Core Labour Standards. Paris____. 1995a. Trade and Labour Standards: Report on a meetingof trade union experts held under <strong>the</strong> OECD Labour/Management Program. Paris: OECD.____. 1995b. Trade and Labour Standards: A Review of <strong>the</strong> Issues.Paris: OECD.Pean, Leslie and Peter Watson. 1993. ‘Promotion of small-scaleenterprises in Senegal’s building and construction sector:The ‘AGETIP’ experience.’ In Helmsing and Kolstee, 1993.Pradhan, B. K, P.K. Roy, and M.R. Saluja. 1999. ‘In<strong>for</strong>mal Sectorin India: A Study of Household Saving Behaviour.’Contribution of <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector to <strong>the</strong> Economy, ReportNo. 1. New Delhi: National Council of Applied EconomicResearch.Ranis, Gustav. 1995. ‘Ano<strong>the</strong>r Look at <strong>the</strong> East Asian Miracle.’ TheWorld Bank Economic Review, Vol. 9, No. 3, pp. 509-534.Roaring, Elena. 2003. ‘Government Regulatory System and <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector.’In Yu, Sandra (ed.). Challenge of In<strong>for</strong>mal W<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong> Philippines.Manila: International Labour Office.Saavedra, J. and M. Torero. 2004. ‘Labour Market Re<strong>for</strong>ms and TheirImpact over Formal Labour Demand and Job MarketTurnover: The Case of Peru.’ In Heckman J. J. and C. Pagés(eds.). <strong>Law</strong> and Employment. Lessons <strong>for</strong> Latin Americaand <strong>the</strong> Caribbean. London: University of Chicago Press:193


131—182.Sabel, C., D. O’Rourke, and A. Fung. 2000. ‘Ratcheting LabourStandards: Regulation <strong>for</strong> Continuous Improvement in <strong>the</strong>Global W<strong>ork</strong>place.’ 23 February draft.Sator, Vanessa and Marilou Renales. 2003. ‘Improving W<strong>ork</strong>ingConditions in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector.’ In Yu, Sandra, ed.,Challenge of In<strong>for</strong>mal W<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong> Philippines. Manila:International Labour Offi ce.Sengenberger, Werner. 2005. ‘Globalization and Social Progress: TheRole and Impact of International Labour Standards.’Second revised and extended version. Bonn: Friedrich EbertStiftung, September.Sethuraman, S. V. (1997) ‘Urban Poverty, and <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector: ACritical Assessment of Current Strategies.’ Available fromILO at http://www.ilo.org/public/english/employment/recon/eiip/publ/1998/urbpover.htmSingh, N. 2003. ‘The Impact of International Standards : A Survey ofEconomic Theory.’ in K. Basu, H. Horn, L. Roman and J.Shapiro (eds.) International Labour Standards, Blackwell,Ox<strong>for</strong>d.Stiglitz, J. 2001. ‘Employment, Social Justice, and Societal Well-Being.’Keynote Speech to <strong>the</strong> ILO Global Employment Forum, 1-3November, ILO Geneva.Sudharshan C. and S.V. Sethuraman. 2001. ‘Social Protection and <strong>the</strong>In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector in Developing Countries: Challenges andOpportunities.’ Social Protection Discussion Paper Series.Washington: The World Bank. December.Sugden, Robert. 1998. ‘Spontaneous order.’ Journal of EconomicPerspectives, 3: 85-97.Tajgman, David. 2006. ‘Extending labour law to all w<strong>ork</strong>ers: promotingdecent w<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy in Cambodia,Thailand and Mongolia.’ Bangkok: International LabourOffi ce.Thanachaisethavut, B and V. Charoenlert. 2006. ‘Extending LabourProtection to <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy in Thailand.’ In DavidTagjman (ed.), Extending Labour Protection to All W<strong>ork</strong>ers:Promoting Decent W<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy inCambodia, Thailand and Mongolia. Bangkok: InternationalLabour Offi ce.Tokman, Victor. 2006. ‘Chile: A promising design towards <strong>the</strong> legalempowerment of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.’ Paper prepared <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> United Nations Commission of Legal Empowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor.____. 2007a. ‘Legal Empowerment Policies: On Labour Rights.’ Paperprepared <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> United Nations Commission of LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. May.____. 2007b. ‘From In<strong>for</strong>mality to Modernization.’ In Towards Full andDecent Employment. London: Zed Books and Hyderabad:Orient Longman and Penang: Third World Netw<strong>ork</strong>, inassociation with <strong>the</strong> United Nations, New Y<strong>ork</strong>:Tomei, Manuela. 2005. Indigenous and tribal peoples: An ethnic auditof selected Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers. Geneva:International Labour Offi ce.Trebilcock, Anne. 2006. ‘Using Development Approaches to Address<strong>the</strong> Challenge of <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy <strong>for</strong> Labour <strong>Law</strong>.’ InDavidov, G and B. Lagnille (eds.), Boundaries and Frontiersof Labor <strong>Law</strong>: Goals and Means in <strong>the</strong> Regulation of W<strong>ork</strong>.Oregon: Hart.____. 2005. ‘Decent W<strong>ork</strong> and <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy.’ DiscussionPaper No 2005/04, UNU-WIDER, Helsinki.____, 2004. ‘International Labour Standards and <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>malEconomy.’ In Les normes internationales du travail: unpatrimoine pour l’avenir. Mélanges en l’honneur de NicolasValticos. Geneva: International Labour Organisation. 585-613UN-Habitat. 2006. Analytical Perspective of Pro-poor Slum UpgradingFramew<strong>ork</strong>s. Nairobi, UN-Habitat and Cities Alliance.February.United Nations Research Institute <strong>for</strong> Social Development (UNRISD).2005. Gender Equality: Striving <strong>for</strong> Justice in an UnequalWorld. New Y<strong>ork</strong>: UNRISD.Viénot, M. 1995. « Rapport sur le Conseil d’Administration des Sociétéscotées. » Revue de Droit des Affaires Internationales 8:372.Wailes, Nick. 2002. ‘Globalization and National Patterns of IndustrialRelations: The Case of Australia,’ in Roger Blanpain (ed),‘The Impact of Globalization on Employment Relations: AComparison of <strong>the</strong> Automobile and Banking Industries inAustralia and Korea.’ Published in a special issue of <strong>the</strong>Bulletin of Labour Relations, Vol. 45.World Bank. 2005. Doing Business in 2005: Removing Obstacles toGrowth. An Overview. World Bank, International FinanceCorporation and Ox<strong>for</strong>d University Press.__________. 2007. In<strong>for</strong>mality: Exit and Exclusion. The World Bank,2007.World Bank. 2007. ‘Enterprise Surveys Online Database.’ http://www.enterprisesurveys.org/__________. 2005. A Better Investment Climate <strong>for</strong> <strong>Everyone</strong>, 2005World Development Report. The World Bank.__________. 2002a. Voices of <strong>the</strong> Poor. Washington, DC.__________. 2002b. ‘Empowerment and Poverty Reduction: ASourcebook.’ World Bank, 2002. Washington, DC. http://go.worldbank.org/FD9HH8DH11W__________. 2001. World Development Report 2000/2001: AttackingPoverty. Washington, DC.Yu, S. and A. Karaos. 2004. ‘Establishing <strong>the</strong> role of communitiesin governance: <strong>the</strong> experience of <strong>the</strong> Homeless People’sFederation Philippines.’ Urbanization and Environment. Vol.16 No. 1, April.194


ChapterFOURBusiness Rights195


EXECUTIVE SUMMARY‘The opposite of poverty is not wealth — it is justice. The objective…is to create a more just society,not necessarily a wealthier one. And <strong>the</strong> great question is how do we do this?’Leonardo Boff, Franciscan Theologian, BrazilW<strong>ork</strong> is central to our lives. Earning alivelihood is not only a basic need,it is a requirement <strong>for</strong> enriching oursense of well-being and <strong>the</strong> quality of life in general.Underpinning a system that contributes toemployment generation and to <strong>the</strong> ability to earna living are <strong>the</strong> savings, investment and innovationundertaken largely by businesses. 1Persistent poverty is <strong>the</strong> result of both publicpolicy failure and market failure. The two arerelated as prevalent policies and <strong>the</strong> resultingsystem of governance, institutional structure andlegal rights tend to characterise and limit <strong>the</strong>function of <strong>the</strong> economy, markets and businesses,and define what <strong>the</strong>y can do and what <strong>the</strong>yare allowed to do.This report attempts to outline how legal mechanismscan empower millions of w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor whoapply initiative and entrepreneurship to earn <strong>the</strong>irliving in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector of economies across<strong>the</strong> world. It begins by outlining <strong>the</strong> barriers thatentrepreneurs face in accessing opportunities in<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economic system. Case studies arepresented to illustrate some solutions and innovations;<strong>the</strong>y are intended to be studied, adaptedand scaled up. The report concludes by underliningessential principles and key considerations inmoving re<strong>for</strong>m frontiers towards more inclusive,gender responsive and integrated economies.After examining current policy re<strong>for</strong>m in privatesector development as well as innovation in institutionaldesign and business linkages, our w<strong>ork</strong>inggroup <strong>for</strong> this chapter concluded that legalempowerment of in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses can serveto promote rights-based economic empowerment.Legal recognition of labour and commercial rightsof business and its incorporation into governanceinstitutions should be at <strong>the</strong> core of legal mechanismsto empower in<strong>for</strong>mal business.Productivity and protection can and should bepromoted toge<strong>the</strong>r. This two-pronged approachcould help to remove barriers in <strong>the</strong> wider legal/regulatory/market environment; it could do this bychanging or simplifying registration and licensingprocedures and extending greater legal rights to<strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor. This would serve to empower<strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor to know and demand <strong>the</strong>ir legalrights, negotiate with officials, bargain more effectivelyin market transactions, and en<strong>for</strong>ce contractsor seek redress when contracts are violated.It would also permit <strong>the</strong>m to be represented inrelevant policymaking and rule-setting bodies.196


In<strong>for</strong>mal and <strong>for</strong>mal businesses are inextricablylinked. There are a variety of reasons <strong>for</strong> lack ofadherence to legal and regulatory requirementsby in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses. Non-compliance meansgreater profits <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses, or it couldbe that <strong>the</strong> requirements are irrelevant, inappropriate,or non-existent <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses.Possibly, in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses cannot af<strong>for</strong>d tocomply with <strong>the</strong> regulations. Also, many do notknow what is required, or <strong>the</strong>y may be unsureas to what advantages <strong>the</strong>re could be under‘<strong>for</strong>mal’ status. Because of <strong>the</strong> uncertainties,in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses continue to chart out <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong>ir own operational support, building netw<strong>ork</strong>sand in<strong>for</strong>mal contractual arrangements groundedmore on social mores than on any legal basis.Legal, policy and regulatory re<strong>for</strong>m and innovation,derived from what w<strong>ork</strong>s <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor andwhat would guarantee <strong>the</strong>ir fundamental rights,is long overdue. Millions of w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor men andwomen have no knowledge of what rights <strong>the</strong>yare guaranteed under national and internationallaw, or of government obligations to provide orfacilitate infrastructure, as well as financial,technical, and business services. With support ofcivil society organisations, or through <strong>the</strong>ir ownassociations, <strong>the</strong>y are beginning to demand some<strong>for</strong>m of legal identity or protection <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>mselvesand <strong>the</strong>ir livelihood activities.The response is a re<strong>for</strong>m agenda that prioritisesapproaches to achieving <strong>the</strong> objectives,and determines <strong>the</strong> order in which <strong>the</strong> selectedmeasures are to be introduced. This would serveto optimise <strong>the</strong> productive potential of in<strong>for</strong>malentrepreneurs and facilitate <strong>the</strong> protection of<strong>the</strong>ir businesses. As <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> objectives, <strong>the</strong>y arebroadly listed as follows: reducing regulatoryburdens; removing unnecessary barriers to <strong>for</strong>malmarkets and institutions; increasing opportunities<strong>for</strong> business linkages; increasing benefits andprotections <strong>for</strong> all w<strong>ork</strong>ing in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector;streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong> organisation and representationof <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal entrepreneurs, and providingequal access of w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor women and men toall of <strong>the</strong> above.Additionally, improvement in <strong>the</strong> quality of institutionsin an economy has to proceed simultaneouslywith <strong>the</strong> trans<strong>for</strong>mation of <strong>the</strong> nature andefficiency of its in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Learning frominstitution-building experiences of industrialisedcountries and those in transition as well from o<strong>the</strong>rdeveloping countries, can be valuable. Thereare some good-practice examples from around<strong>the</strong> world that illustrate how <strong>the</strong> constraintsof in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses have been successfullyaddressed through successful institutional andpolicy changes. At <strong>the</strong> same time, national andlocal level institutional changes can be initiatedimplicitly with <strong>the</strong> introduction of new economicactivities that may well provide direct and measurablebenefits.The In<strong>for</strong>mal EntrepreneurStreet vendors, rural milk hawkers, millers andginners, small food cart pushers, shoe shiners,<strong>the</strong> itinerant fix-it technician, <strong>the</strong> roadside hairdresserand food caterer — <strong>the</strong>se are <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malentrepreneurs who are vibrant visible economicplayers in <strong>the</strong> poorer countries of <strong>the</strong> world. Asan observer suggests, <strong>the</strong>y are ‘<strong>the</strong> true entrepreneurs— more flexible, efficient and resilient than<strong>the</strong> over-regulated and overprotected dinosaursof <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal sector....’ 2 These entrepreneurs arecalled in<strong>for</strong>mal because <strong>the</strong>y operate to some extentoutside <strong>the</strong> realm of <strong>for</strong>mal legal regulationand protection, and without easy or full access to<strong>the</strong> advantages of <strong>for</strong>mal financial and businesssupport systems.There are some 500 million w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor earningless than one dollar per day (ILO 2004). The197


vast majority earn <strong>the</strong>ir living in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy, occupying land <strong>the</strong>y do not own, w<strong>ork</strong>ingin small, in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses, and relying onfamily or friends <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal moneylenders <strong>for</strong>loans. Often, <strong>the</strong>y have limited access to broadereconomic opportunities and are especially vulnerableto <strong>the</strong> uncertainties, <strong>the</strong> corruption and even<strong>the</strong> violence prevalent outside <strong>the</strong> rule of law.They have little or no access to settling disputesusing <strong>the</strong> legal machinery. Without legal rights orprotections, <strong>the</strong>y are in a continual state of legaland political vulnerability. In<strong>for</strong>mality, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e,limits <strong>the</strong> opportunity <strong>for</strong> economic and socialdevelopment <strong>for</strong> individuals, families, businesses,communities, and even entire nations.The ILO defines <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy as accommodating‘all economic activities that are —inlaw or practice- not covered or insufficiently coveredby <strong>for</strong>mal arrangements.’ 3 It includes wagew<strong>ork</strong>ers and own-account w<strong>ork</strong>ers and contributingfamily members. In<strong>for</strong>mal entrepreneurs are<strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor who run very small enterprises.These include micro-entrepreneurs who hirew<strong>ork</strong>ers and two kinds of own-account operators,namely, heads-of-family businesses and singlepersonoperators.Around <strong>the</strong> developing world, women tend tobe concentrated in <strong>the</strong> low-end <strong>for</strong>ms of ownaccountw<strong>ork</strong>, and <strong>the</strong>y are under-representedamong micro-entrepreneurs. On average, earningsin in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises are low while costs andrisks are high, particularly <strong>for</strong> own-account operators,but especially <strong>for</strong> women operators.Legal Empowerment and LegalIdentityLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor, such that <strong>the</strong>irentrepreneurship is linked to greater economicopportunity, means not only re<strong>for</strong>m in legal codesbut also policies to correct asymmetries in accessto in<strong>for</strong>mation, education and training, and accessto financial, technical and business services.Additionally, <strong>the</strong> vast assortments of legal andregulatory rules and administrative systems, inwhich businesses are embedded, have to beexamined. A fundamental premise to all changeis that <strong>the</strong> legal identity of individuals as citizensand as entrepreneurs or w<strong>ork</strong>ers must be clearlyestablished. For example, identity verificationis essential to commercial dispute resolutionprocedures and to local governance concerns.Similarly, property rights have ‘to be given toactual people, who <strong>the</strong>mselves — in order to advanceand defend <strong>the</strong>ir access to and possessionof such rights — first must be able to <strong>for</strong>mallyverify <strong>the</strong>ir personal status and identity. A crucialpre-requisite, <strong>the</strong>n, to enhancing <strong>the</strong> quality ofproperty rights is ensuring that residents/citizenshave recognised documents (such as birth, death,marriage and divorce certificates) verifying suchbasic in<strong>for</strong>mation as <strong>the</strong>ir name, age, sex andmarital status.’ 4Based on evidence, we argue that <strong>the</strong>re is need<strong>for</strong> an effective and enabling environment, regulatoryregime, commercial law and good economicgovernance <strong>for</strong> allowing business to operate wi<strong>the</strong>quitable economic rights and guaranteeinggreater accountability in <strong>the</strong> government’s abilityto issue laws and <strong>the</strong> capacity to implement anden<strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong>m. This process should empower <strong>the</strong>poor to use law and legal tools to prevail overpoverty, while persuading <strong>the</strong> government toequitably en<strong>for</strong>ce its policies and regulations andrein<strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> role of <strong>the</strong> civil society in implementinggreater accountability of all actors andat all levels. Sound economic governance is builtupon principles of equity and equality of opportunities.Public policies and action <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e mustsupport access to and distribution of assets, economicopportunities, and political voice participa-198


tion in decision making that promote sustainableenterprises. In order to effectively address <strong>the</strong>challenge to ‘level <strong>the</strong> playing field,’ governancestructures have to emphasise greater investmentin <strong>the</strong> human resources of <strong>the</strong> poor, guaranteeson business rights <strong>for</strong> all and fairness in markets.Countries with pervasive inequalities in wealth,resources, weak institutions, and power typicallyexperience narrow financial sectors that meet<strong>the</strong> needs of <strong>the</strong> privileged and <strong>the</strong> influential.Among <strong>the</strong> many market failures in developingcountries, notable are those in <strong>the</strong> financial marketsincluding those <strong>for</strong> credit, insurance, land,and human capital. With <strong>the</strong> consolidation ofmarket power in a limited number of large banks,lending tends to get biased in <strong>the</strong> favour of enterprisesthat are low risk and may exclude thosewith <strong>the</strong> highest expected risk-adjusted returns.Access to finance is essential <strong>for</strong> businesses;however businesses in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy lackaccess to financial markets and <strong>the</strong> capacity tocompete in product markets.The higher <strong>the</strong> levels of inequities, <strong>the</strong> greaterwould be <strong>the</strong> propensity of <strong>the</strong> institutionsand social arrangements to favour <strong>the</strong> interestsof <strong>the</strong> influential and <strong>the</strong> privileged. Inequitableinstitutions generate economic costs, which areavoidable. It is <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e important to make surethat business rights do not provide exclusivebenefits and are not en<strong>for</strong>ced selectively so that,both middle and poorer groups end up with unexploitedcapacity.An Integrated Economy ApproachLegal empowerment measures have to take placewithin a policy and regulatory approach whichrecognises that <strong>the</strong> two parts of <strong>the</strong> economy —<strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>mal — do not exist independentlyof each o<strong>the</strong>r. There is a constant exchange ofideas, people, skills, goods and services between<strong>the</strong> two parts. At <strong>the</strong> base of <strong>the</strong> private sectorare millions of small, micro, and mini entrepreneurs,who provide <strong>the</strong> bulk of <strong>the</strong> raw material<strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal sector production, engage intermittentlyas labour in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal enterprises, anduse products made in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal sector. Thosewho have been employees in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal sectorand have acquired new techniques, capabilitiesand business contacts, often move into <strong>the</strong> moreflexible in<strong>for</strong>mal sector and set up <strong>the</strong>ir own businesses.If relationships between different levelsof economic activity are to be anticipated, madestrategic and optimized, policy and institutionalchange <strong>for</strong> sustained business linkages and skillsdevelopment has to take place. Those who w<strong>ork</strong>in <strong>the</strong> micro-enterprises, and own-account w<strong>ork</strong>erswithin supply chains that lead into <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>malsector, have to be accorded legal protection ona par with enterprises and w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>malsector.Successful design and support of appropriate policiesand institutions <strong>for</strong> an integrated economymust begin with analysis of innovations emergingat <strong>the</strong> interface between <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal and <strong>for</strong>mal.Small producers and micro-entrepreneurs aredaily developing strategies <strong>for</strong> dealing with <strong>the</strong>demands of <strong>for</strong>mal institutions, while <strong>the</strong> latterhave also developed ways of managing <strong>the</strong>ir inevitableencounter with those who are <strong>the</strong> majorityin <strong>the</strong> poorer countries of <strong>the</strong> world. These copingstrategies hold clues as to what developmentinterventions can and should build upon, within<strong>the</strong> context of particular cultures, economies andindustries. Contextual specificity and lessonsfrom on-<strong>the</strong>-ground experience, are importantprinciples <strong>for</strong> policy and institutional innovations<strong>for</strong> an integrated and inclusive economy.Analysis of current practice could provide guidance<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> move from a bifurcated to an integrated,cohesive approach to entrepreneurship199


and economic activity. First, in order to encouragegreater engagement between established<strong>for</strong>mal businesses and <strong>the</strong> smaller enterprises,transaction costs and risks of such engagementhave to be reduced. Second, <strong>the</strong> public sectorhas to develop and implement participatoryprocesses so that support is relevant to those on<strong>the</strong> fringes of <strong>for</strong>mal activity. Third, change hasto be negotiated through iterative dialogue andpartnerships spanning across central and localgovernments, <strong>the</strong> private sector, domestic capitalmarkets, producer groups and <strong>the</strong>ir social andeconomic organisations. Fourth, <strong>the</strong> function inmicro and small scale entrepreneurial activity of‘immediate and direct reciprocities’ 5 has to berecognised; in many low-income communities,economic activities and arrangements are embeddedin social relationships. How social relationsand values, not just market <strong>for</strong>ces, affect <strong>the</strong>modus operandi of millions of entrepreneurs hasto be brought into economic re<strong>for</strong>m considerations.How social and cultural norms condition<strong>the</strong> modes of production and overall situation ofwomen entrepreneurs and indigenous peoples isparticularly pertinent to this consideration.The Re<strong>for</strong>m AgendaOur w<strong>ork</strong>ing group <strong>for</strong> Chapter 4 of this reportrecommends <strong>the</strong> following as key messages in <strong>the</strong>legal empowerment of in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses:1. Policy Stance• Legally empowering small in<strong>for</strong>mal businessesrun by poor individuals or households shouldbe seen as a central pillar of a just societyand a central strategy <strong>for</strong> reducing poverty andinequality.• Most policies and <strong>the</strong> global economy currentlyaccord privilege to large firms/enterprises oversmall firms/enterprises.• In<strong>for</strong>mality is here to stay and is an essentialfeature of <strong>the</strong> global economy.• Poverty and exclusion go hand in hand. Thepoor have no choice but to accept insecurityand instability as a way of life. Our re<strong>for</strong>magenda reflects <strong>the</strong> realities of poverty andexclusion experienced by poor people, and<strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e focuses on removing <strong>the</strong> barriers thathold <strong>the</strong> poor back, and building a framew<strong>ork</strong>of laws and institutions to provide genuineprotection and opportunity <strong>for</strong> all. This will requirewholesale systemic changes to all facetsof <strong>the</strong> legal framew<strong>ork</strong>, including: <strong>the</strong> politicalprocess, economic policy, law making, publicadministration, and law en<strong>for</strong>cement.• While national governments and <strong>the</strong> internationalcommunity should seek to create asmany <strong>for</strong>mal jobs as possible and <strong>for</strong>malise asmany in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises and jobs as possible,in<strong>for</strong>mality is not going to disappear. The realchallenge will be to reduce <strong>the</strong> ‘decent w<strong>ork</strong>deficits’ of those who w<strong>ork</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mally, especially<strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor.• Poor people’s enterprise does play a vital role in<strong>the</strong> economies of many countries, and <strong>the</strong> poor<strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e have a right to earn a living free fromharassment, extortion, beating, wrongful eviction,expropriation and exploitation. They mustbe offered equal opportunity to access local,national and international markets.• Commercial rights <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal entrepreneurs/operators should be seen as an essential partof a package of rights <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poorin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. This would includeproperty rights, labour rights, <strong>the</strong> right to socialprotection, and <strong>the</strong> right to organise and to berepresented in policymaking and rule-settinginstitutions and processes.• O<strong>the</strong>r than social protection (property, health,life, disability, old age) that is relevant <strong>for</strong> wage200


w<strong>ork</strong>ers as well as <strong>the</strong> self-employed in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy, commercial rights are relevantto <strong>the</strong> half of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy who are self-employed.• Of <strong>the</strong> half of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor who are self-employed,<strong>the</strong> larger and more vulnerable groupare own-account operators, including bothsingle person operators and those who w<strong>ork</strong> infamily businesses or on family farms.• Productivity and protection can and should bepromoted toge<strong>the</strong>r.• Economic policies should address issues ofredistribution.• Legal empowerment will stimulate growthwhich is on its turn a pre-condition to reducepoverty.2. Policy Positions• On basic commercial rights: right to w<strong>ork</strong>,including right to vend; right to a w<strong>ork</strong> space(including public land and private residences)and to related basic infrastructure (shelter,electricity, water, sanitation).• On intermediary commercial rights: right togovernment incentives and support (includingprocurement, tax holidays, export licensing,export promotion), and right to public infrastructure(transport and communication).• On advanced commercial rights: entity shieldingrules, limited liability and capital lock-inrights, mechanisms <strong>for</strong> perpetual successionof <strong>the</strong> firm and transferring its value, mechanismsto allow <strong>the</strong> use of standardised accounting,mechanisms to establish firm, managerand employee liability rights, protect minorityshareholders and default rules.3. Policy Process• Seeks to reduce <strong>the</strong> ‘decent w<strong>ork</strong> deficits’ ofthose who run in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses.• Includes representative voices of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ingpoor in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.• Recognises and addresses bias in existing commercialpolicies, regulations, laws, and proceduresthat favour larger firms/enterprises.• Seeks to extend government incentives andprocurements to <strong>the</strong> smallest in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises.• Seeks to build backward and <strong>for</strong>ward linkageson fair terms between larger and smaller firms.• Promotes social protection <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal operators(property, health, life, disability insurance),and does retraining, life-long learning and o<strong>the</strong>rsupport to mobility.4. Practical StrategiesGood practice examples from around <strong>the</strong> worldcould help in devising local needs-based modelsto address local issues and constraints.5. Policy DebatesDebates on <strong>for</strong>malisation of in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses.Formalisation could take on different <strong>for</strong>ms,including:• Expanding <strong>for</strong>mal employment opportunities.• Creating incentives <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises to<strong>for</strong>malise, such as:• Simplified registration procedures and progressiveregistration fees.• Supportive investment climate.• Fair commercial transactions between in<strong>for</strong>malenterprises and <strong>for</strong>mal firms.• Appropriate legal and regulatory framew<strong>ork</strong>s,including en<strong>for</strong>ceable commercial contracts,property rights and use of public space.• Tax-funded incentives, including: govern-201


ment procurement, tax rebates, and taxfundedsubsidies and incentive packages.• Provision of financial, business and marketingservices.• Creating mechanisms and financial arrangementsto provide social protection <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malproducers.• Promoting participatory policy processes andinclusive rule-setting institutions that involverepresentatives of associations of in<strong>for</strong>malentrepreneurs.The broad effect of re<strong>for</strong>m in attaining legal empowermentwill not only improve <strong>the</strong> well-beingand livelihoods of individual entrepreneurs; it willalso result in enhanced social protection, as wellas increased productivity and asset base of poorpeople and of <strong>the</strong> nation as a whole.I. Introduction andFramew<strong>ork</strong>Since <strong>the</strong> phrase ‘in<strong>for</strong>mal sector’ was coinedin <strong>the</strong> early 1970s 6 to describe <strong>the</strong> range ofsubsistence activities of <strong>the</strong> urban poor, <strong>the</strong>re hasbeen considerable debate about its definition.The in<strong>for</strong>mal sector is not homogenous; it encompassesdifferent types of economic activities,different labour relations that range from <strong>the</strong> selfemployed,paid and unpaid, to disguised wagew<strong>ork</strong>ers and economies with different economicpotential that includes survivalist economies andsuccessful micro and small enterprises. In effect,<strong>the</strong> term ‘in<strong>for</strong>mal economy’ is more appropriateas it comprises <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector while notexcluding possible linkages of in<strong>for</strong>mal operatorswith <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal sector. 7Generally speaking, in<strong>for</strong>mal economyencompasses <strong>the</strong> expanding an increasinglydiverse groups of w<strong>ork</strong>ers and businesses inboth rural and urban areas, operating in<strong>for</strong>mally— i.e., <strong>the</strong>y are not recognised or protectedunder <strong>the</strong> legal and regulatory framew<strong>ork</strong>s. Thenational and local economies continue to be acontinuum that ranges from in<strong>for</strong>mal to <strong>for</strong>mal.The in<strong>for</strong>mal economy has been growing at arapid rate throughout <strong>the</strong> world, including in <strong>the</strong>industrialised countries. In recent years, much of<strong>the</strong> employment potential within <strong>the</strong> developingcountries has been found in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economiesand, hence, in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises.In <strong>the</strong>se countries, a much higher proportion ofthose w<strong>ork</strong>ing in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy are poor,with <strong>the</strong> share of women relative to men beingmuch higher.202Accordingly, <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agenda<strong>for</strong> business rights emphasises re<strong>for</strong>ms, creatingmechanisms and financial arrangements toprovide social protection <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal producers.


Good initiatives have been undertaken by ILO,<strong>the</strong> World Bank, USAID, among o<strong>the</strong>r organisations,to provide <strong>the</strong> poor and <strong>the</strong> disadvantagedwith <strong>the</strong> legal and institutional environment and<strong>the</strong> rule of law in order that <strong>the</strong>y might betterdevelop <strong>the</strong>ir capacity to use <strong>the</strong>ir own talents,energy and initiative <strong>for</strong> accessing livelihoodresources, and assets to generate efficient andproductive enterprises. The ultimate goal is toguarantee sustainable livelihoods <strong>for</strong> all — along<strong>the</strong> continuum from <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal to <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>maleconomy. The approach: reorienting gender-baseddevelopment strategies to eradicate poverty. Thisrequires 1) a better understanding of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malbusinesses and enterprises within <strong>the</strong> context of<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>mal continuum, and 2) an integrativestrategy to design a system of businessrights that provides solutions to <strong>the</strong> lack of socialprotection, lack of representation and voice,and leads to more efficient economic functioning,greater trust and reduction in conflict, andimproved institutions with dynamic benefits <strong>for</strong>equitable investment and growth.This chapter on Business Rights presentsevidence to demonstrate that <strong>the</strong> inequality ofbusiness opportunities available to <strong>the</strong> poor isuneconomical and detrimental to sustainabledevelopment and poverty reduction. It will alsoprovide policy and rule of law implications emergingfrom removal of bureaucratic and administrativeinefficiencies in <strong>the</strong> life cycle of businessesand <strong>the</strong> study of market failures, particularly at<strong>the</strong> local levels, while building upon <strong>the</strong> broadconcept of levelling <strong>the</strong> playing field — politicallyand economically — in <strong>the</strong> domestic and globalarenas.Why Business Rights? And why now?We live in world of increasing inequities. Therichest two percent of adults own more than 50percent of global assets. The poorest half of <strong>the</strong>population holds only one percent of wealth. 8Unprecedented affluence co-exists with astonishingdeprivation, persistence of poverty and unmetbasic needs, violation of fundamental politicalfreedoms, and neglect or even absence of lawfulprivileges that uphold basic civil liberties <strong>for</strong> asignificant proportion of <strong>the</strong> population. Nearly40 percent of <strong>the</strong> world’s 6.5 billion peoplelive in poverty of which, a sixth live in extremepoverty. 9 The number of people living in extremepoverty in Africa has nearly doubled from 164million in 1981 to 316 million in 2001. Even <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong> world, extreme poverty today hasincreased by nearly three percent from 1981. 10While <strong>the</strong> deprivations indicated above are morecommon in <strong>the</strong> less wealthy countries, <strong>the</strong>y existin, one <strong>for</strong>m or ano<strong>the</strong>r, in rich countries too. 11W<strong>ork</strong>, being central to our lives, is a basic requirementto enriching human well-being and <strong>the</strong>quality of life in general. W<strong>ork</strong> empowers peopleto enhance <strong>the</strong>ir ability to attain and sustainlivelihoods, while it is largely left to business tocreate savings, investment and innovation thatcontribute to livelihoods and to employmentgeneration. 12 Persistent poverty may be blamedon both public policy failure and market failure.Interestingly, <strong>the</strong> two are related in that prevalentpolicies and resulting systems of governancestructure and legal rights have largely served tocharacterise <strong>the</strong> function of <strong>the</strong> economy, marketsand businesses, and to define what <strong>the</strong>y cando and what <strong>the</strong>y are allowed to do. There<strong>for</strong>e,an integral constituent of poverty reduction musthave to do with empowering <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor toaccess opportunities that could be created byreducing economic, legal and social inequalities.Businesses, generally speaking, constitute <strong>the</strong>private sector; <strong>the</strong>y are usually led private individuals,communities and corporations. In many203


developing countries, however, in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprisesovershadow <strong>the</strong> private sector and <strong>the</strong>irnumber is increasing. Creation of good qualityjobs is determined to a large extent by enterprisecreation, innovation and expansion. Where <strong>the</strong>potential <strong>for</strong> entrepreneurship, creativity, dynamicand productive job creation is stifled, ei<strong>the</strong>rthrough onerous legal procedures and institutionsor through inequities represented by vested interestsand inadequate en<strong>for</strong>cement, entrepreneurswill gravitate towards <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.In<strong>for</strong>mal firms and enterprises account <strong>for</strong> morethan 50 percent of all economic activities andsome estimates conclude that over 30 percent of<strong>the</strong> developing world’s GDP and 70 percent of itw<strong>ork</strong>ers are outside <strong>the</strong> official economy. 13 Thesize of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy is inversely relatedto economic development and, while, at <strong>the</strong>same time, <strong>the</strong>re is a significant correspondencebetween w<strong>ork</strong>ing in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy andbeing poor. However, a large number of in<strong>for</strong>malbusinesses in an economy are not per se a sign ofits underdevelopment; <strong>the</strong>y are, ra<strong>the</strong>r, a reflectionof <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>se enterprises are confinedto subsistence and insufficiently productiveactivities.In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy and In<strong>for</strong>malBusinessesThe in<strong>for</strong>mal economy in Africa is estimated tohave been 42 percent of GDP in 2000. WhileZimbabwe, Tanzania and Nigeria were at <strong>the</strong> highend with <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector representing 59.4percent, 58.3 percent and 57.9 percent of respectiveGDP, Botswana and Cameroon were at <strong>the</strong>lower end, with 33.4 percent and 32.8 percentrespectively. At <strong>the</strong> turn of <strong>the</strong> century, 93 percentof <strong>the</strong> jobs created in Sub-Saharan Africa werein <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, 14 with almost 80 percentof non-agricultural employment and over 60percent of urban employment. 15 In Latin America,<strong>the</strong> average size of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy was 41percent of GDP with Bolivia as <strong>the</strong> largest in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy at 67.1 percent, and Chile as <strong>the</strong>smallest at 19.8 percent. In Asia, <strong>the</strong> range variedfrom Thailand at 52.6 percent, to Singapore with13.1 percent. In transition countries, by far <strong>the</strong>largest in<strong>for</strong>mal economy was in Georgia with 67.3percent, and at <strong>the</strong> lower end were <strong>the</strong> Czech Republicwith 19.1 percent and <strong>the</strong> Slovak Republicwith 18.9 percent.In <strong>the</strong> recent years, <strong>the</strong> lion’s share of newemployment in developing countries has beenin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Activities in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy provide certain benefits to a marginalfew. Also, while some activities in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy provide viable livelihoods with reasonableincomes <strong>for</strong> some, most in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers earninsecure incomes under conditions that are not onpar with decent w<strong>ork</strong> standards. 16 They do not, <strong>for</strong>example, receive medical or o<strong>the</strong>r benefits. 17 In effect,<strong>the</strong> decent w<strong>ork</strong> deficits are most pronouncedin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy where most w<strong>ork</strong>ers havelittle or no social protection and receive little orno social security. Also, poor respect and lack offreedom of association make it difficult <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>sew<strong>ork</strong>ers and <strong>the</strong>ir employers to organise. 18 In addition,w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economyare often unsafe, uncertain, and poor in terms ofremuneration. O<strong>the</strong>r concerns are poor occupationalhealth and safety arrangements, and realfears <strong>for</strong> sexual harassment and violence againstwomen. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, wages are suppressed belowadequate levels and fail to reward productivity orlong service. 19 Finally, <strong>the</strong> lack of social protectionmeasures, such as rights and representation,leave many in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong>ce trapped inpoverty. 20 Nearly all in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers are among<strong>the</strong> poorest citizens of <strong>the</strong>ir respective countries,and <strong>the</strong>y lack education, money and <strong>the</strong> ability to204


obtain <strong>for</strong>mal, permanent w<strong>ork</strong>. 21 It is importantto add that a larger proportion of women relativeto men w<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy and suffersfrom poverty.Legal Empowerment and BusinessRightsThe in<strong>for</strong>mal economy includes a growing andincreasingly diverse group of w<strong>ork</strong>ers and ruraland urban enterprises operating in<strong>for</strong>mally. While<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy comprises both productionunits of various kinds and elements of employmentstatus, this paper will focus mainly on businessrights relating to small entrepreneurs and<strong>the</strong> self-employed. Business rights are integralcomponents of <strong>the</strong> strength of an economy. Whilemillions in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy may be wagelabourers, consisting of paid, unpaid and disguisedwage recipients in ‘value chains’, engagedin survival-type activities, <strong>the</strong>re are never<strong>the</strong>less asignificant proportion of poor people who are selfemployedin micro-enterprises, operating <strong>the</strong>irown business ventures, or contributing familyw<strong>ork</strong>ers, or employees.The problems and needs under each of <strong>the</strong>secategories may be different, but <strong>the</strong>y never<strong>the</strong>lessfall into <strong>the</strong> ‘in<strong>for</strong>mal’ category because <strong>the</strong>ylack recognition or protection under <strong>the</strong> legal,institutional and regulatory, judicial and disputeresolution framew<strong>ork</strong>s. They also lack access to<strong>the</strong> advantages of <strong>for</strong>mal financial and businesssupport systems. In addition, <strong>the</strong>y are excludedfrom, or have limited access to, public infrastructureand o<strong>the</strong>r benefits of <strong>the</strong> public goods aswell as to markets and <strong>the</strong>y are <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e unableto be competitive or efficient in managing <strong>the</strong>iractivities. This, in turn increases <strong>the</strong>ir vulnerabilityto natural, social and political shocks andstresses and places doubt on <strong>the</strong> sustainability of<strong>the</strong>ir livelihoods.It is argued that prevalence and increase in in<strong>for</strong>malbusiness is a consequence of inequitablepolicies and discriminatory en<strong>for</strong>cement that failto give support to those businesses and entrepreneurialopportunities in which tangible benefitsmight accrue to <strong>the</strong> poor. Accordingly, <strong>for</strong> mostsmall entrepreneurs and self-employed people,w<strong>ork</strong>ing in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy is a survivalstrategy ra<strong>the</strong>r than an option.Balancing Human Rightsand Market-Based ApproachLegal empowerment aims to address relativedeprivation in all <strong>for</strong>ms, including social,political and economic dimensions in <strong>the</strong> pursuitof a life of choice, freedom, respect and dignity.The issue of equity, in having rights and beingable to en<strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong>m, is critical, as it relatesto <strong>the</strong> disparities in capabilities which reflectson access to wealth and resources as well as toownership of assets. While <strong>the</strong> rich and privilegedcan protect <strong>the</strong>mselves and <strong>the</strong>ir rights by legalmeans as well as by influence and connections,<strong>the</strong> poor must rely on legally en<strong>for</strong>ceable rights.The recognition of human rights is <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e necessary.Equally necessary are <strong>the</strong> legal means andcapacities to en<strong>for</strong>ce those rights through accessibleand effective institutions and processes thatare transparent, participatory and accountable.At <strong>the</strong> same time, institutional re<strong>for</strong>ms designedto eradicate poverty need to be put into place toensure that state and public policies w<strong>ork</strong>, thatregulation to create greater equity is in place, andthat <strong>the</strong> system will w<strong>ork</strong> to help <strong>the</strong> poor and <strong>the</strong>disadvantaged to create wealth — even throughentrepreneurship.Public investments are crucial <strong>for</strong> developing thatkind of ‘private based economy’ that could allow<strong>the</strong> private sector to create employment and sustainlong- term economic growth. In <strong>the</strong> absence205


of <strong>the</strong> provision of adequate infrastructure, healthservices and education, market <strong>for</strong>ces alone canaccomplish little. Existence of markets is a prerequisite<strong>for</strong> survival and sustainability of businessesand entrepreneurs. While <strong>the</strong> freedom toenter a market 22 is a vital constituent of development,<strong>the</strong> level of access and representation inthose markets determines <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal or in<strong>for</strong>malcharacter of an enterprise and what it can accomplish.Again, <strong>the</strong> markets cannot functionin <strong>the</strong> absence of effective and equitable publicpolicy, rule of law, regulation, social support andpolitical freedoms. In principle, <strong>the</strong> markets, inaddition to creating economic efficiency, can alsoencourage greater economic equity. This would,however, depend on <strong>the</strong> structure of markets,<strong>the</strong>ir governance and associated legal rights, and<strong>the</strong> nature and extent of <strong>the</strong>ir inclusiveness asreflected through active business enterprises.Private institutions are willing to develop innovativepartnership models to provide greater accessto goods and services by <strong>the</strong> poor. But <strong>the</strong>y requireassistance through appropriate policies andstreng<strong>the</strong>ned capacities to remove barriers to <strong>the</strong>market creation and provide greater market accessto <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurs in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economies.At <strong>the</strong> same time, governments shouldnot hesitate to step in, possibly in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m ofpublic-private partnerships, that would encourageprivate institutions to meet <strong>the</strong> demands of<strong>the</strong> poor and enhance market access in rural andunderserved areas 23 .Economic success requires getting <strong>the</strong> balanceright between <strong>the</strong> government and <strong>the</strong> market,in terms of who should provide <strong>the</strong> goods andservices and how <strong>the</strong>y should be provided. Anysuccessful development strategy demands <strong>the</strong>existence of equitable access to markets by alland requires involvement of government, marketsand <strong>the</strong> private sector, and <strong>the</strong> civil society.Voice, Representation and EffectiveEconomic GovernanceIt is essential to build upon and refine <strong>the</strong> aboveissues in <strong>the</strong> context of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong> of <strong>the</strong> Commissionon Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor (CLEP)and re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> development agenda by broadening<strong>the</strong> discussion of business rights and <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy in a comprehensive manner thatgoes beyond <strong>for</strong>malisation per se. It will emphasisethat <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor tocreate and operate <strong>the</strong>ir enterprises and generatesustainable livelihoods sustainably requires <strong>the</strong>mto have a voice in all aspects of policymaking,implementation and en<strong>for</strong>cement, and to have<strong>the</strong> ability to w<strong>ork</strong> with governments and o<strong>the</strong>rstakeholders to create new rights, capacities, andopportunities.The adverse effects of unequal opportunitiesof representation and political voice andpower <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poorer people on human developmentare particularly harmful because economic,political, and social inequalities tend to reproduce<strong>the</strong>mselves over time and across generations,setting into motion a poverty trap that doesnot allow <strong>for</strong> improvements in <strong>the</strong> quality of <strong>the</strong>irlives.Business rights should result in <strong>the</strong> creation ofan efficient and inclusive private sector with asound domestic macro environment, having tradepolicies, institutional foundations and adequatecapacity <strong>for</strong> maximising benefits from <strong>the</strong> macroglobal environment and promoting distributionalequity.There is evidence, we believe, to argue <strong>the</strong> case<strong>for</strong> an effective and enabling environment, <strong>for</strong> aregulatory regime and <strong>for</strong> commercial law, as wellas good economic governance that would allowbusiness to operate with equitable economicrights and guarantee greater accountability in206


<strong>the</strong> government’s ability to issue, implement anden<strong>for</strong>ce laws. This would empower <strong>the</strong> poor to uselaw and legal tools to prevail over poverty, whilepersuading <strong>the</strong> government to equitably en<strong>for</strong>ceits policies and regulations and rein<strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> roleof <strong>the</strong> civil society in implementing greater accountabilityof all actors and at all levels. Soundeconomic governance is built upon principlesof equity and equality of opportunities. Publicpolicies and action, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, must supportaccess to and distribution of assets, economicopportunities, and political voice participation indecision-making that w<strong>ork</strong>s to promote sustainableenterprises. In order to effectively address<strong>the</strong> challenge of ‘levelling <strong>the</strong> playing field’,governance structures have to emphasise greaterinvestment in <strong>the</strong> human resources of <strong>the</strong> poor,guarantees <strong>for</strong> business rights <strong>for</strong> all, and fairnessin markets.Greater Access to Markets, Goods andServices, and InfrastructureIt is vital to have functional legal principles andmechanisms that will enable entrepreneurs andbusinesses in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy to havegreater access to goods and services and marketsso <strong>the</strong>y can build productive and efficient businessenterprises. At <strong>the</strong> minimum, this requires<strong>the</strong> existence of equitable opportunities <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>poor to create, run and manage a business. Inturn, it translates into streng<strong>the</strong>ned capabilitiesof <strong>the</strong> poor to access and effectively useresources, infrastructure, and constituent components24 of a business and factors of production.With such assurances, <strong>the</strong>y could efficientlytrans<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong>ir labour into a successful business.They could manage it to obtain certain profit, anduse <strong>the</strong> secure asset base to expand that businesssuccessfully. For a business to be sustainable,<strong>the</strong> entrepreneur should have <strong>the</strong> abilityto manage a high level of personal, professionaland financial risk, as well as <strong>the</strong> risk of physical,environmental and socially adverse impacts,in addition to <strong>the</strong> capacity to recover from thoseshocks.In <strong>the</strong> presence of missing or imperfect markets,<strong>the</strong> distribution of wealth and power affects <strong>the</strong>allocation of investment opportunities. Achievingeconomic efficiency would necessitate <strong>the</strong> combinationof actions relating to correction of <strong>the</strong> marketfailure as well as measures to provide greateraccess to services, assets, and political influenceby <strong>the</strong> disenfranchised suffering from adverseimpacts of inequitable development strategies.Inclusive Financial ServicesCountries with pervasive inequalities in wealth,resources, weak institutions, and power typicallyexperience narrow financial sectors that meet <strong>the</strong>needs of <strong>the</strong> privileged and <strong>the</strong> influential. Among<strong>the</strong> many market failures in developing countries,<strong>the</strong> most notable are those in <strong>the</strong> financialmarkets, including those in <strong>the</strong> areas of credit,insurance, land, and human capital. With <strong>the</strong>consolidation of market power in a limited numberof large banks, lending tends to get biased in <strong>the</strong>favour of enterprises that are low risk. This mayexclude those with <strong>the</strong> highest expected risk-adjustedreturns. Access to finance is essential <strong>for</strong>businesses; however businesses in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy lack access to financial markets and <strong>the</strong>capacity to compete in product markets.Over 4 billion people globally are currently irrelevantto <strong>the</strong> banking system. Normally, accessto commercial banks by <strong>the</strong> low income andrural populations is limited in terms of physicaldistance to <strong>the</strong> closest branch of <strong>the</strong> bank andalso because of thresholds in account fees orminimum required balances. While large companiesare well served by existing banking system,low income and rural individuals, micro-entre-207


preneurs and small sector enterprises are particularlyunder-serviced by <strong>the</strong> financial industry.For instance, nearly 741 million Indians in ruralareas are poorly served, despite a huge demand<strong>for</strong> financial services, including an estimated annualcredit demand exceeding US$10 billion. 25Similarly, those in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy are notcovered by safety and health regulations and arenot, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, eligible <strong>for</strong> social security benefits,pensions or o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>ms of social protection.Enhanced access to basic financial services— savings, credit, insurance, pensions andtools <strong>for</strong> risk management — is a critical input <strong>for</strong>emerging and potential entrepreneurs to leverageeconomic opportunities and improve <strong>the</strong>ir qualityof life. The ability and willingness of private financialinstitutions to provide access to inclusivefinancial services would depend on appropriatepolicies, existence of relevant human and institutionalcapacities that would remove barriersto <strong>the</strong> market creation, as well as incentives topartner with <strong>the</strong> private sector to provide broadermarket access to <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurs who requiregreater facilitation and empowerment. At <strong>the</strong>same time, <strong>the</strong> government should not hesitate tostep in through policies, regulations and incentivesto encourage private financial institutionsto garner savings, long term credit and marketbasedsocial protection instruments in rural andunderserved areas. 26 The regulatory structures,<strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, have to ensure broader access to financialservices, particularly <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor, as well asa deepening of <strong>the</strong> financial sector and establishmentof greater accountability.Institutional ChangesThe higher <strong>the</strong> levels of inequities, <strong>the</strong> greaterwould be <strong>the</strong> propensity of <strong>the</strong> institutions andsocial arrangements to favour <strong>the</strong> interests of<strong>the</strong> influential and <strong>the</strong> privileged. Inequitableinstitutions generate economic costs, which areavoidable. It is <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e important to make surethat <strong>the</strong> business rights do not provide exclusivebenefits and are not en<strong>for</strong>ced selectively, whichwould leave both middle and poorer groups withunexploited capacity.As <strong>the</strong> realms of institutional and economicdevelopment are reciprocally related, knowledgeof national and local contexts is critical. There<strong>for</strong>e,international comparisons of ‘ease of doingbusiness’ need to take into account <strong>the</strong> realityof <strong>the</strong> nature, quality and experience of differentcountries. Although <strong>the</strong> private sector in developingcountries is largely comprised of in<strong>for</strong>malbusinesses, <strong>the</strong> character and attributes of <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal sector will most certainly vary from onecountry to <strong>the</strong> next. It would <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e appear that<strong>the</strong> effectiveness of recommendations on <strong>the</strong> convenienceof doing business should be measuredby <strong>the</strong> extent to which <strong>the</strong> proposed changesare mainstreamed and translated into improvedper<strong>for</strong>mance of <strong>the</strong> institutions and <strong>the</strong>ir operatingenvironment. Without such measure, <strong>the</strong>expected increase in <strong>for</strong>eign investment would beillusory.Because <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy and in<strong>for</strong>mal businessesare predominantly local, <strong>the</strong> criteria determiningease of doing business must incorporate<strong>the</strong> needs of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses. Subsequentrecommendations should <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e encompassand be judged by <strong>the</strong> ability of <strong>the</strong> macro-levelchanges to <strong>the</strong> business climate to impact locallevelinstitutions and, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, businesses in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.Improvement in <strong>the</strong> quality of institutions in aneconomy has to proceed simultaneously with <strong>the</strong>trans<strong>for</strong>mation of its in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Valuablelessons can be learned from <strong>the</strong> institution-buildingexperience of <strong>the</strong> industrialised countries208


and those in transition, as well as from o<strong>the</strong>rdeveloping countries. There are good-practiceexamples from around <strong>the</strong> world that illustratehow constraints of in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses have beensuccessfully addressed through institutional andpolicy change. At <strong>the</strong> same time, national andlocal level institutional changes can be initiatedimplicitly by launching new economic activitiesthat provide direct and measurable benefitsto those who will be influenced by institutionalchange. As <strong>the</strong> process continues, <strong>the</strong> ability ofa population, impacted by institutional change,to realise tangible benefits will provide proof of<strong>the</strong>ir ownership. Over time, <strong>the</strong> economic activitybecomes an agent <strong>for</strong> and a catalyst of demand<strong>for</strong> appropriate institutions. 27 For instance, economicempowerment based on economic activityis a step towards gender equality, 28 even if <strong>the</strong>yare not synonymous. Linking creative economicactivities with business rights in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy has an added advantage in that it allowslearning-by-doing in implementing institutionalre<strong>for</strong>ms. It also allows <strong>for</strong> synergistic linkages betweenre<strong>for</strong>ms from above (including those initiatedby governments or promoted by internationalorganisations) with effective action from below(by civil society organisations and organisationsof <strong>the</strong> poor <strong>the</strong>mselves).Pursuing <strong>the</strong> Agenda <strong>for</strong> ChangeThe emphasis of <strong>the</strong> document is placed oncreating larger options and opportunities <strong>for</strong>entrepreneurs and businesses in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomies to operate proficiently and equipping<strong>the</strong>m with capabilities, enabling environmentand equitable governance systems to make correctchoices to maximise <strong>the</strong>ir welfare. 29TheLegal Empowerment Framew<strong>ork</strong> does not look to<strong>for</strong>malising economies as <strong>the</strong> desired outcome;instead, it urges <strong>the</strong> creation of circumstances inwhich <strong>the</strong> ultimate benefits of <strong>the</strong> developmentinterventions will accrue in equitable manner to<strong>the</strong> poor on a sustainable basis.An important focus of <strong>the</strong> paper on BusinessRights is <strong>the</strong> use of an evidence-based approach.It is anticipated that <strong>the</strong> analysis will establishempirical linkages to illustrate legal rights andempowerment of <strong>the</strong> poor by tackling <strong>the</strong> intricacyof <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy and proposing amethodology and sequence of actions to address<strong>the</strong> underlying complex issues of in<strong>for</strong>mal businessesand poverty alleviation.The ‘agenda <strong>for</strong> change’ proposes a comprehensivestrategy to address three inter-relatedcomponents that run <strong>the</strong> continuum from<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal to <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal end of <strong>the</strong> economy;<strong>the</strong>y include:• Creating more entrepreneurship and businessopportunities by ensuring that those in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy are legally recognised; <strong>the</strong>yshould have legal social protection and riskmanagement options, equitable representationand voice, as well as and assurances that <strong>the</strong>new enterprises do not have an incentive to bein <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector simply because of lowercost.• Enabling those enterprises currently in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy to move upwards along <strong>the</strong>continuum, through a context-specific mix oflegal policy framew<strong>ork</strong>s that include incentivesand regulations, as well as assurances that <strong>the</strong>entrepreneurs have <strong>the</strong> capacity and flexibilityto do so.• Improving productivity, efficiencies and conditions,and increasing <strong>the</strong> returns <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> businessesin <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector.It is obvious that <strong>the</strong> interventions under <strong>the</strong>three categories will have common characteristics.The guiding principle would be to tackle <strong>the</strong>root causes of in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses ra<strong>the</strong>r than209


negative manifestations of in<strong>for</strong>mal businessesand in<strong>for</strong>malisation. Also, <strong>the</strong> changes have tooccur at <strong>the</strong> local level, which basically defines<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Successful mobilisation ofbusinesses at local level, whe<strong>the</strong>r by <strong>the</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>tsof government, private sector or NGO, is a greatpromoter of equitable economic growth. Whilesuch interventions would be local in nature, <strong>the</strong>irimplementation recognises <strong>the</strong> global (universal)context that influences all development activities.In <strong>the</strong> end, <strong>the</strong> success and sustainabilityof any re<strong>for</strong>m will depend on public recognitionand ownership of evidence-based trans<strong>for</strong>mationwithin <strong>the</strong> cultural, social and political milieu. 30To Sum UpThis introduction provided an overall framew<strong>ork</strong>on <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agenda <strong>for</strong> businessrights and sets <strong>the</strong> stage <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sections thatfollow. We proposed that re<strong>for</strong>ms can help <strong>the</strong>poor and <strong>the</strong> disadvantaged with <strong>the</strong> legal andinstitutional environment and <strong>the</strong> rule of law.People would <strong>the</strong>n be encouraged to develop<strong>the</strong>ir capacities, energies and initiatives and toaccess livelihood resources, build assets andgenerate efficient and productive enterprises. Thenext section will look at in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses andenterprises within <strong>the</strong> context of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal-<strong>for</strong>malcontinuum; it will examine <strong>the</strong> relationshipbetween <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, poverty and productivity,and it will map <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economiesthat involve women and indigenous people.2. In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy andIn<strong>for</strong>mal BusinessesIn<strong>for</strong>mal-Formal ContinuumEven though any debate on ‘in<strong>for</strong>mality’ centreson <strong>the</strong> dichotomy between <strong>for</strong>mal andin<strong>for</strong>mal, <strong>the</strong> concept is a lesser representative ofdualism and embodies a continuum when viewedfrom any of <strong>the</strong> perspectives of activities, institutionsor contracts. The definition of in<strong>for</strong>mality,however, is ambiguous and in<strong>for</strong>mal economydenotes a plurality of activities that are also contextual.The term ‘in<strong>for</strong>mal sector’ is inadequatebecause it fails to represent <strong>the</strong> inherent heterogeneity,complexity and dynamism of this economyand its constituent activities. Also, <strong>the</strong> genderbias in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy is probably underestimatedand women are more likely to be in thosein<strong>for</strong>mal activities that are under-counted, includingproduction <strong>for</strong> own consumption and paiddomestic activities in private households. Basedon <strong>the</strong> ILO’s classification, 31 <strong>the</strong> term ‘in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy’ has come to be widely used to include<strong>the</strong> expanding and increasingly diverse group ofw<strong>ork</strong>ers and enterprises in both rural and urbanareas, operating without recognition under legaland protective framew<strong>ork</strong>s, and characterised bya high degree of vulnerability.The in<strong>for</strong>mal economy is differentiated in termsof production units as well as employment status.In<strong>for</strong>mal may <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e refer to firm features oftypes of firms, or it may refer to employment. Itmay also be characterised as an activity or a typeof activity. On <strong>the</strong> one hand, it includes own-accountw<strong>ork</strong>ers in survival type activities, rangingfrom street vendors, cobblers and shoe shiners,garbage collectors and rag pickers, to <strong>the</strong> selfemployedentrepreneurs. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong>range of wage earners — from aid domestic w<strong>ork</strong>-210


ers employed by households, to ‘disguised wagew<strong>ork</strong>ers’ employed by sweatshops in productionchains — are also included as important constituentsof <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.Not surprisingly, any discussion of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy would include ‘small’ enterprises notregulated, as well as employment relationshipsthat are not legally recognised and that leavemuch to be desired (in terms of providing socialprotection and reduction of vulnerability). Wemay note here that issues relating to employability,productivity and flexibility of <strong>the</strong> labour<strong>for</strong>ce and to <strong>the</strong>ir upward movement along <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal-<strong>for</strong>mal continuum are <strong>the</strong> subject ofChapter 3 of this report on Labour Rights. Thethrust of this discussion, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, will maintain<strong>the</strong> focus on in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses and enterpriseswhich, <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> purpose of analysis, include ownaccountoperators. We examine legal measuresthat include <strong>the</strong> presence of, and equitable accessto, effective judicial, political and economic,market and non-market institutions. These, wehave observed, make it easier <strong>for</strong> micro and smallenterprises to start up and grow in a manner thatallows <strong>the</strong>m to adopt ‘high road’ strategies toenhance efficiency and productivity and providedecent jobs <strong>for</strong> its employees.Poverty and In<strong>for</strong>mal EconomyIncreasing poverty spurs growth of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy. In turn, <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy promoteseconomic growth, serving to reduce poverty. Theproblem here is that any reduction in poverty isinefficient, and lacks legal recognition, regulationand protection. Studies of countries that havesuccessfully delivered pro-poor growth suggestthat even though economic growth is extremelyimportant, it is unable, by itself, to address <strong>the</strong>eventual disparity in poverty reduction. It is necessaryto address <strong>the</strong> nature of inequalities whileaccounting <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> resulting change, if any, ininequality from this kind of economic growth. 32In<strong>for</strong>mation and data on <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economyin developing countries is sketchy since very fewcountries undertake survey of employment andengagement in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy on a regularbasis. Even though nearly 75 percent of <strong>the</strong> poorpeople in developing countries live in rural areasand engage in in<strong>for</strong>mal economic activities relatedto agriculture, many countries exclude agriculturefrom <strong>the</strong>ir measurement of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.33An in<strong>for</strong>mal sector survey carried out by ILOin 1995 found that 41 percent of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>erswere in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy because <strong>the</strong>ycould not find any o<strong>the</strong>r w<strong>ork</strong> (including thosewho became involved following <strong>the</strong>ir retrenchment),30 percent because <strong>the</strong>ir family neededadditional income, 10 percent because of <strong>the</strong>freedom to determine <strong>the</strong>ir hours or place ofw<strong>ork</strong>, and 9 percent because of good incomeopportunities. 34 Although not all poor are in<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, almost all those who arein<strong>for</strong>mal are poor. Urban areas of most developingcountries expose <strong>the</strong> contemporaneous existenceof in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers’ shacks with <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers’more affluent homes. In <strong>the</strong> name of economicdevelopment and en<strong>for</strong>cement of propertyrights, <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mer are first to be destroyed by governmenteven though <strong>the</strong> services provided to <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mal settlements by <strong>the</strong>m are perfectly legal.In<strong>for</strong>mal EnterprisesDespite <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> self-employed andemployers face many barriers to setting up andoperating in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises, <strong>the</strong>y account <strong>for</strong>70 percent of <strong>the</strong> jobs in sub-Saharan Africa andabout 60 percent in <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r developing regions.In India, nearly 93 percent of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce is in<strong>the</strong> self-organised in<strong>for</strong>mal sector, with nearly 10211


million persons and <strong>the</strong>ir dependents relying onstreet vending <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir livelihood. 35Studies alsoindicate that in <strong>the</strong> absence of in<strong>for</strong>mal economies,a majority of private sector householdswould have fallen deeper into poverty. 36There is a prevalent assumption that in<strong>for</strong>malenterprises exist by choice because of <strong>the</strong>owners’ preference to curtail labour costs andavoid payment of taxes. While this is true, it isnot <strong>the</strong> entire story. Many businesses in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy have limited output, employment orincome to even be at <strong>the</strong> level of taxable entities.The root causes of <strong>the</strong> manifestation of in<strong>for</strong>malenterprises encompass <strong>the</strong> legal and institutionalhurdles that make it difficult to become or stay<strong>for</strong>mal. For instance, <strong>the</strong> regulatory environmentmay be excessively burdensome, overly punitiveand especially, in <strong>the</strong> cases of crises countries,non-existent. In addition, in<strong>for</strong>mal businesseshave little access to public infrastructure and dependon in<strong>for</strong>mal and unfair institutional arrangements<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir essentials. Essentials could rangebroadly from credit, markets and non-marketinstitutions, training, developing skills and knowledge,to social protection, and even in<strong>for</strong>mationon demographic trends (including rural-urbanmigration and cross-border labour migration), andnational policies that constrain or limit employmentgeneration in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy.Lack of registration and regulation of in<strong>for</strong>malbusinesses and enterprises prevents in<strong>for</strong>malw<strong>ork</strong>ers from enjoying <strong>the</strong> rights of <strong>the</strong> decentw<strong>ork</strong> that may be accorded under <strong>the</strong>ir nationallabour legislation. The use of <strong>the</strong> term ‘in<strong>for</strong>mal’does not mean an absence of norms or rules <strong>for</strong>operations of <strong>the</strong> enterprises. Businesses in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy have <strong>the</strong>ir own institutions,mechanisms, rules, financial arrangements, andsystems <strong>for</strong> accessing technology and markets,but <strong>the</strong>y lack a common framew<strong>ork</strong> and it is unclearif <strong>the</strong>y observe <strong>the</strong> fundamental and humanrights of <strong>the</strong> labour. Also a number of criminalactivities — money laundering, human and drugtrafficking, tax evasion, etc. — are in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy, as <strong>the</strong>y operate on <strong>the</strong> fringes of <strong>the</strong>law. This area, however, is beyond <strong>the</strong> scope ofour chapter.In<strong>for</strong>mal Enterprises and ProductivityA large in<strong>for</strong>mal sector can be an indication ofhigh regulatory costs on business, raising doubtson <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong> regulations <strong>the</strong>mselves. Studies37 have found that <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malsector, also termed ‘shadow economy’, could beinversely related to Gross Development Product(See Figure 1). In<strong>for</strong>mality restrains efficient useof resources and productivity. The inefficiency orsub-optimal productivity of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economyis <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e linked in part, to <strong>the</strong> absence of legalprotection, inability to en<strong>for</strong>ce contracts and <strong>the</strong>need <strong>for</strong> security that comes from <strong>the</strong> dearth ofproperty rights and decent w<strong>ork</strong> attributes. Theirability to organise <strong>for</strong> social protection is weak,with little or no voice to make <strong>the</strong>ir businessrecognised or protected. The lack of voice andparticipation in decision-making leads to nonexistenceof economic rights or opportunities toachieve <strong>the</strong>ir full economic potential.An economy with a large proportion of in<strong>for</strong>malbusinesses functions below its potential, with alower rate of economic growth. 38 It also servesto point up systemic inequities in <strong>the</strong> abilityof entrepreneurs to access markets, resources,technology, in<strong>for</strong>mation, public infrastructureand social services. However, <strong>the</strong> large number ofsmall firms in developing countries is not in itselfa sign of <strong>the</strong>ir underdevelopment, but, ra<strong>the</strong>r, areflection of <strong>the</strong>ir confinement to insufficientlyproductive activities.It is important to design policies and mechanisms212


Figure 1 GDP Per Capita and <strong>the</strong> Size of <strong>the</strong> Shadow EconomyGDP per capita (constant 1995 US$50 00045 000•40 000•35 000Norway30 000••25 000Belgum• • • • •20 000•15 000• UK •••10 000• •5 000Estonia Hungary• PeruGuatemala EgyptI I • • • ••• • • I••• • •• • •I •• • •• •I Tunisia • I I • • I• • I0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80Size of <strong>the</strong> shadow economy (% of GDP) Source: Erneste & Schneider 1998Figure 2 Indigenous private sector development and regulation in Africa and Central Europe:a 10-country studyGDP Per Capita growth rate against sum of policy and institutions to improve <strong>the</strong> enablingenvironment: 1995-1999GDP Growth rate 1995-19996%5%4%3%2%1%0%• Uganda• Poland• Latvia• HungaryMalawi•Ghana•• Tanzania4 I ZambiaSouth Africa• Kenya6 I •8 I 10 I 12 I 14 I 16 I 18 IPolicy and institutions Source: Bannock, G. et al. August 2002that enable <strong>the</strong> participation and access to benefitsfrom growth by <strong>the</strong> poor people. This requiresa conscious and sustained ef<strong>for</strong>t by governmentsto create necessary conditions <strong>for</strong> broad-basedgrowth in regions and sectors where <strong>the</strong> poor liveand w<strong>ork</strong>. 39 While it is not guaranteed that <strong>the</strong>adoption of <strong>the</strong> favoured institutional and policymix will bring higher GDP growth, studies showthat differences in policy and policy implementationare reflected in dramatically different rates ofgrowth of GDP per capita achieved. Appropriateregulatory and institutional environment has beenfound to be <strong>the</strong> single most important elementin an economic growth strategy. Even thougha country’s level of skills, especially technicalskills, is also strongly correlated with per capitaeconomic growth, interventions to improve <strong>the</strong>national regulatory and institutional environment213


within which business operates offer far morerapid impact scenarios than those based on longerterm education and skills strategiesA Mapping of In<strong>for</strong>mal Economies 40Although, <strong>the</strong> studies that describe countrylevel patterns and changes have at best beensketchy, given <strong>the</strong> complexity of measuring <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economies precisely, <strong>the</strong>y are certainlyindicative. Over <strong>the</strong> last fifteen years or so, <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal sector in Sub-Saharan Africa has apparentlyincreased from about two-thirds to nearlythree-quarters of non-agricultural employment. 41Street vending predominates, with women traders<strong>for</strong>ming <strong>the</strong> majority in many of <strong>the</strong> countries in<strong>the</strong> region. Former retailing establishments oftenencourage in<strong>for</strong>mal economy operators to expand<strong>the</strong>ir markets to low income groups and ruralareas who can be reached most easily by itineranttraders and street vendors.In<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises are small-scale enterpriseswith 80 percent classified as a one-person business.Businesses with more that one person weremainly found to be in transportation and construction.For women in this region, <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy presents 92 percent of <strong>the</strong> total job opportunitiesoutside of agriculture compared to 71percent <strong>for</strong> men. Almost 75 percent of <strong>the</strong>se jobsare per<strong>for</strong>med as self-employed and own-accountw<strong>ork</strong>ers, and only 5 percent as paid employees.Most small scale enterprises are without a <strong>for</strong>malestablishment: over 33 percent of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malactivities take place within or beside <strong>the</strong> homeof <strong>the</strong> business operator; 20 percent are withouta fixed location; 10 percent are at a market, and10 percent are in <strong>the</strong> street or in an open space.The major sources of livelihoods, especially<strong>for</strong> women engaged in in<strong>for</strong>mal activities (foodprocessing, handicrafts, hawking and vending),have been affected by trade liberalisation and bycross-border trading. Cross-border trading is verysignificant in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy and is prevalentin South Africa and West Africa. For instance,a large number of temporary immigrants purchasegoods in South Africa to take back to <strong>the</strong>ir owncountries <strong>for</strong> sale. While normally <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maltrade is within <strong>the</strong> region itself, traders from WestAfrica travel as far as Dubai and China to purchasehigher quality goods that are cheap. 42 Also,vendors in Africa now have opportunities to link upwith bigger enterprises and transnational corporationsto become a part of <strong>the</strong>ir value chain. 43In Latin America, urban in<strong>for</strong>mal employmentincreased from 52 percent in 1990 to 58 percentin 1997 as a proportion of <strong>the</strong> total urbanemployment. 44 Not surprisingly, <strong>the</strong> increase wasalso observed in employment in micro and smallenterprises as well as growth in self-employment.A proportion of self-employment or own-accountw<strong>ork</strong>ers is an indicator of low job growth in <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mal economy and a high rate of employmentcreation in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Self-employmentrepresents nearly 32 percent of totalnon-agricultural employment worldwide, with 44percent in Latin America. 45 In poor countries likeBangladesh and Pakistan, <strong>the</strong> proportion of selfemploymentaccounts <strong>for</strong> nearly 70 percent of<strong>the</strong> total employment.In <strong>the</strong> transition countries of Central and EasternEurope and <strong>the</strong> countries of <strong>the</strong> Commonwealthof Independent States (CIS), <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economyranges from subsistence farming, petty trade,undeclared and unregistered labour, unregulatedand unlicensed enterprises, <strong>the</strong> shuttle trade withneighbouring countries, to tax evasion. With <strong>the</strong>transition of <strong>the</strong> region to a market economy, <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy has expanded rapidly becauseof economics and social trans<strong>for</strong>mations, closureof many state- owned enterprises, increasedprivatisation, labour retrenchment and collapse of214


social insurance, and need <strong>for</strong> institutional, businessand labour re<strong>for</strong>ms that have lacked en<strong>for</strong>cementand failed to keep in touch with changingeconomic realities.The expansion of manufacturing and industryhas led to a relative decline in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy in China, Japan, <strong>the</strong> Republic of Koreaand Singapore. While <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy hadalso declined from 60 to 57 percent in Thailandfrom 1980 and 1994 because of <strong>the</strong> economicboom, with <strong>the</strong> effect of <strong>the</strong> economic recessionof 1997 it grew again to 60 percent. 46 Althougheconomic recession leads to an increase in‘survivalist’ economic activities suggesting <strong>the</strong>poverty mitigating role of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy,economic prosperity has also been directly relatedto an increase in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, asin Indonesia, because of increased opportunitiesand <strong>the</strong> ability of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises to respondto new market opportunities. An expansionof <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mer circumstancesreflects marginalization of economic activitiescharacterised by low productivity, low incomesand low standards of living. 47 On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rhand, expansion of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy duringan economic boom is related to <strong>the</strong> expediencyof bypassing over-bearing bureaucratic processesand business practices that can constrain firmsin <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy from responding quickly tomarket signals and increasing demand.Women in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal EconomyWorldwide, women’s share of in<strong>for</strong>mal economyemployment has remained between 60 percentand 80 percent. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> number of femalesin <strong>the</strong> labour <strong>for</strong>ce is continuously on <strong>the</strong> rise andwomen in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy most probablynumber much more than reflected in availablestatistics. (Girls, too, would be among <strong>the</strong>ir numbers.)They comprise most of <strong>the</strong> unpaid labour,are often home-based w<strong>ork</strong>ers, and thus fall easilythrough gaps in enumeration as data and statisticson household level is still difficult to measure. Inmany countries, women are also drawn to <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy because <strong>the</strong>y lack <strong>the</strong> right to ownand inherit property and are <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e obstructedfrom activity in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy, as <strong>the</strong>y donot have assets to use as security <strong>for</strong> credits, etc.A statistical snapshot of women in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy around <strong>the</strong> world reveals: 481) In<strong>for</strong>mal employment is generally a largersource of employment <strong>for</strong> women than <strong>for</strong> menin <strong>the</strong> developing world. O<strong>the</strong>r than in <strong>the</strong> MiddleEast and North Africa, where 42 percentof women w<strong>ork</strong>ers are in in<strong>for</strong>mal employment,60 percent or more of women w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong>developing world are in in<strong>for</strong>mal employment(outside agriculture). The comparative figures<strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal employment, as share of non-agriculturalemployment by sex and region, areas follow: in sub-Saharan Africa, 84 percentof women w<strong>ork</strong>ers compared to 63 percent ofmen w<strong>ork</strong>ers; in Latin America, 58 percent ofwomen w<strong>ork</strong>ers, 48 percent of men w<strong>ork</strong>ers,and in Asia, 73 percent of women to 70 percentof men.2) Although women’s labour-<strong>for</strong>ce participationrates are lower than men’s, <strong>the</strong> limited dataavailable points to <strong>the</strong> importance of women inhome-based w<strong>ork</strong> and street vending in developingcountries: 30-90 percent of street vendors,except in societies that restrict women’smobility; 35-80 per-cent of all home-basedw<strong>ork</strong>ers, including both self-employed andhome w<strong>ork</strong>ers; and 80 percent or more of homew<strong>ork</strong>ers — industrial outw<strong>ork</strong>ers who w<strong>ork</strong> athome).3) Although women’s labour <strong>for</strong>ce participationrates are lower than men’s, women represent<strong>the</strong> vast majority of part-time w<strong>ork</strong>ers in many215


developed countries. In 1998, women were60 percent or more of part-time w<strong>ork</strong>ers in allOECD countries reporting data. Women’s shareof part-time w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> specific countries was ashigh as 98 percent in Sweden, 80 percent in<strong>the</strong> United Kingdom, and 68 percent in bothJapan and <strong>the</strong> United States.Indigenous Peoples and In<strong>for</strong>malBusinessesAlthough <strong>the</strong> concept of social exclusion hasgained wide currency, over 370 million indigenouspeoples continue to be marginalized from<strong>the</strong> benefits of mainstream social and economicdevelopment. Indigenous peoples are over-representedamong <strong>the</strong> poor in over 70 countries.Lacking secure property rights hinders indigenouspeoples in obtaining compensation fromgovernment in cases of eviction and displacement.Usually, this is due to lack of evidence tosupport <strong>the</strong>ir property rights. They also face hugebarriers in obtaining legal protection (throughen<strong>for</strong>cement opportunities), access to resourcesand wealth creation. Due to past experiencesof bias and discrimination, many indigenouspeoples <strong>for</strong>go <strong>for</strong>mal justice systems; also, legalaid services are often not provided to those livingoutside <strong>the</strong> mainstream justice system. Lack oftitle to property is ano<strong>the</strong>r barrier to economicempowerment. Traditional property rights systemsare being eroded as a result of neo-liberal,macro-economic policies. Indigenous peoplesmust <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e resort to finding employment inoccupations that are not <strong>for</strong>mally paid, as mightbe <strong>the</strong> case in rotational farming, fishing andweaving. Illiteracy and impoverishment fur<strong>the</strong>rlimit employment opportunities in low paid jobs.Indigenous women carry <strong>the</strong> burden of reproductivew<strong>ork</strong>, domestic w<strong>ork</strong>, child care and w<strong>ork</strong>ingin <strong>the</strong> field.Distinct cultural identity and values: The indigenouspeople’s perspectives on property, povertyand development are different from mainstreamthinking and are not based solely on a marketcash-based economy. Many indigenous societiesexchange value (ra<strong>the</strong>r than money) by <strong>for</strong>ms ofbarter, gift exchange, and o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>ms of reciprocalexchange. A better understanding of <strong>the</strong>se‘principles of reciprocity’ would be needed tounderpin <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong> of <strong>the</strong> Commission. This maypose a number of binary oppositions, many ofwhich may be challenged and contested, including:spirituality vs. rationality, collectivity vs.individuality (competition, intellectual propertyclaims), sustainability vs. optimal productivity,traditional knowledge (e.g. trial and error) vs.empirical scientific methodology, subsistencevs. commerciality or markets, custom vs. state,rights vs. poverty, and inclusion vs. exclusion (orassimilation vs. integration).Indigenous peoples often employ innovativemethods to subsist, using traditional knowledgesystems. With <strong>the</strong> onset of globalisation, it atfirst appeared that a new environment would beopened to developing new approaches, but barriersto entrepreneurship remain.Micro-credit and micro-finance institutions areoften <strong>the</strong> only source of capital <strong>for</strong> indigenouspeoples and women in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal and homebasedsectors. However, indigenous peoples’perceptions of credit and loans are often compromisedin <strong>the</strong> interests of entering <strong>the</strong> globaleconomy. Ef<strong>for</strong>ts to promote innovation andentrepreneurship in indigenous peoples’ territoriesshould seek to understand and assess<strong>the</strong> systems of exchanging value in <strong>the</strong> society,sometimes based on complex kinship, culturaland o<strong>the</strong>r social netw<strong>ork</strong>s.216


Box 1 Empowering Indigenouspeoples throughEntrepreneurshipThe ILO-INDISCO Programme was launched in <strong>the</strong>Philippines in 1994 in collaboration with <strong>the</strong> PhilippineGovernment. It is a multi-bilateral technicalcooperation aimed at streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong> self-relianceof indigenous and tribal peoples through entrepreneurialactivity. It has facilitated <strong>the</strong> operation of 12pilot projects in different parts of <strong>the</strong> country, whichinvolve indigenous communities in various stagesof development. Financial and technical assistancehas been provided to indigenous communities toengage in entrepreneurship.The main window of opportunity <strong>for</strong> income andemployment generation opened to community memberswas <strong>the</strong> Revolving Loan Fund, which providesassistance to groups and individuals <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>irlivelihoods activities. Toge<strong>the</strong>r with skills training ona particular trade <strong>the</strong> community wanted to pursue,plus appropriate equipment bought from projectfunds, members of several indigenous communitiesmanaged to improve <strong>the</strong>ir market access and economicstatus. Twelve communities with a combinedpopulation of approximately 90,000 people havebenefi ted directly or indirectly from <strong>the</strong>se projects.An estimated 2,500 jobs in agriculture, traditionalhandicraft, fi shery, weaving and community serviceswere created. As a result of <strong>the</strong> new revenue-generatingactivities, <strong>the</strong> income levels of partnercommunities have increased by an average of 44percent. In recent years, <strong>the</strong> ILO has been providingtechnical assistance to some projects fundedthrough <strong>the</strong> Small Grant Fund from <strong>the</strong> Embassy ofFinland. The fund has supported various projectsproposed by <strong>the</strong> Indigenous communities.Source: ILOEmpowering In<strong>for</strong>mal BusinessesClearly, <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal business economy also links<strong>for</strong>mal sectors to consumers. In fact it providesmany low and middle-income employees of <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mal sector with goods and services and contributesto economic growth. Economic growth,while a necessary condition, is not a sufficientcondition <strong>for</strong> creating productive employment andpoverty reduction. As discussed earlier, an increasein economic growth does not usually resultin <strong>the</strong> alleviation of an in<strong>for</strong>mal economy or <strong>the</strong>transition from in<strong>for</strong>mal to <strong>for</strong>mal unless it alsobrings greater equity. A positive outcome wouldreflect an approach that regards people living inpoverty as creators of growth ra<strong>the</strong>r than merelyas recipients of benefits. 49 We should, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e,focus on empowering <strong>the</strong> poor and <strong>the</strong> disadvantaged,whe<strong>the</strong>r as self-employed producersand entrepreneurs or as employees of a firm. Itis important that <strong>the</strong>se economic actors participatefully and on an equal basis in <strong>the</strong> economicdevelopmentSome of <strong>the</strong> critical barriers faced by firms in<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy include limited humanand w<strong>ork</strong>ing capital, limited access to markets,goods and services and to financial and businesssupport services, obsolete technology, complexand burdensome government regulations with pooren<strong>for</strong>cement, lack of economic infrastructure anda poor supply of public services. Given <strong>the</strong> impedimentsto operate businesses in most developingcountries, <strong>the</strong> opportunity costs of in<strong>for</strong>malityappear to be much lower compared to operating<strong>for</strong>mally. It is <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e not surprising that in<strong>for</strong>malnetw<strong>ork</strong>s also coordinate many transactionsamong <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal enterprises. Emphasis must fallon improving <strong>the</strong> business environment, and in amanner that it is particularly beneficial <strong>for</strong> enterpriseat local level, including <strong>the</strong> rural areas. Forinstance, India’s economic re<strong>for</strong>ms, which alsocover <strong>the</strong> business environment, have generallyfocused on <strong>the</strong> corporate and <strong>the</strong> organised sectorthat provides employment to nearly three percentof <strong>the</strong> country’s w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong>ce, with ano<strong>the</strong>r three to217


four percent employed in <strong>the</strong> public sector andgovernment. The balance, or roughly 93 percentof <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ce, which is essentially <strong>the</strong> self-organisedin<strong>for</strong>mal economy, remains untouched bythose economic re<strong>for</strong>ms. 50Accordingly, it is important to improve <strong>the</strong>economic governance structure that could allowsmaller <strong>for</strong>mal enterprises to grow with greaterefficiency, productivity and quality w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions.It is equally necessary to facilitate <strong>the</strong>problems faced by in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises in accessingproducts offered by financial institutions,such as <strong>the</strong> incorporation of security insuranceand <strong>the</strong> establishment of limited liability institutionsthat might encourage high return-high riskinvestment. In<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises also need to besensitised to <strong>the</strong> requirements <strong>for</strong> improving employmentand w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions so that <strong>the</strong>y areable to access dual labour regulations and safetynets in meeting part of <strong>the</strong>ir own labour contributionswhile sustaining <strong>the</strong> business and generatingdecent employment. 51Similarly, efficiency among <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal enterprisesshould be improved comprehensively and in anintegrated manner by en<strong>for</strong>cing <strong>the</strong> rule of law.This would cover property rights and <strong>the</strong> reductionof corruption by lowering transaction costsof various activities. It would include reducingentry and operating <strong>for</strong>mal costs, reducing growthbarriers and implementing cost-efficient andproficient policies, guidelines and procedures <strong>for</strong>en<strong>for</strong>cement of compliance. If a one-stop shopis a solution <strong>for</strong> reducing registration proceduresand costs, <strong>the</strong>n it is vital that such facilities areorganised and available at different levels (local,municipal, district, national and regional).This would not only facilitate <strong>the</strong> availability ofrelevant in<strong>for</strong>mation, but would also be a disincentiveto operate in<strong>for</strong>mally if cost was <strong>the</strong> solerationale <strong>for</strong> such an action.Awell-structured tax system that is understandableand transparent would also dissuadefirms from adopting <strong>the</strong> inefficiencies ofin<strong>for</strong>mality simply to avoid taxes. Also, if locallevies translate into fees <strong>for</strong> enhancing access tocommunity resources as well as public serviceswith greater accountability, <strong>the</strong> attractiveness andlower opportunity cost of in<strong>for</strong>mal sector woulddiminish significantly.It would also be helpful to introduce propertyrights registration, contract en<strong>for</strong>cement mechanismsand clear policy guidelines to encouragemarket participation of street vendors, etc., ina manner that is participative, and incorporatesin<strong>for</strong>mal and popular rules. By bringing diversegovernance structures within <strong>the</strong> purview of <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mal judicial system in a manner that is accessibleand simple, it would increase <strong>the</strong> reach ofrule of law to all business operators and encourage<strong>the</strong> efficient creation of in<strong>for</strong>mal-<strong>for</strong>mal<strong>for</strong>ward and backward linkages.Given suitable conditions, including provision <strong>for</strong>capacity development, vocational training, andskill building, many in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises mayef<strong>for</strong>tlessly glide into <strong>for</strong>mal ones. This empowermentprogramme has to be an integral componentof poverty reduction strategies using incentivesbased on participation, a level playing field ofregulations, and en<strong>for</strong>cements <strong>the</strong>reof that, interalia, enhances efficient, af<strong>for</strong>dable and reliableaccess to public infrastructure services.While legal identity has been linked to a greateraccess to basic goods and services and opportunities,it could catalyse inclusive developmentonce it becomes a constituent of a larger re<strong>for</strong>magenda. So, legal identity must be internalisedin policies and actions that target <strong>the</strong> integrationof markets of <strong>the</strong> poor with o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>mal markets,<strong>the</strong>reby enabling <strong>the</strong>m to meet <strong>the</strong> unmet de-218


mand <strong>for</strong> af<strong>for</strong>dable financial services. But, in <strong>the</strong>absence of legal documents, it is very unlikelythat emphasis on legal identity would reduceexclusion. 52 Accordingly, <strong>the</strong> challenge to comprehensivelyaddress <strong>the</strong> inter-related componentsof <strong>the</strong> continuum from <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal to <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>malend of <strong>the</strong> economy is not technological; it is instructuring institutions, capacities, incentivesand regulations to provide certainty to economicexchange and <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e to equitable economicgrowth. 53issues highlighted in this section, which also providedan overview of in<strong>for</strong>mal economies around<strong>the</strong> globe. The next section on legal identity andbusiness rights discusses, among o<strong>the</strong>r issues,<strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> an effective enabling environment,regulatory regime, commercial law and good economicgovernance that is required <strong>for</strong> businessto operate with equitable economic rights andwith guarantees of greater accountability in <strong>the</strong>government’s ability to issue laws with <strong>the</strong> capacityto implement and en<strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong>m.Economic growth draws upon activities that arecomplex, fluid and geographically dispersed. Theyrequire an elaborate and ever evolving division oflabour ranging from owners of <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>malenterprises, producers, managers, and <strong>the</strong>iremployees, who are an integral component of <strong>the</strong>value chain. Such a large-scale division of labourrequires state-like institutions <strong>for</strong> public en<strong>for</strong>cementof laws and contracts 54 and <strong>for</strong> its efficientsustainability. Although <strong>the</strong> government takes <strong>the</strong>lead in creating regulations, it is important to engageo<strong>the</strong>r stakeholders, including <strong>the</strong> poor peopleas economic actors, as well as NGOs, localpublic governance structures, and in<strong>for</strong>mal labourassociations. This would ensure ownership by allrelevant actors and create inexpensive approachesto en<strong>for</strong>ce compliance with <strong>the</strong> regulations. Itis <strong>the</strong> inclusive partnerships and a shared agendabetween small and large firms, governments at alllevels, civil society and <strong>the</strong> development agenciesthat will unlock new opportunities. 55To Sum UpIncreasing poverty is a key reason <strong>for</strong> growth of<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy and a main cause of <strong>the</strong>blossoming of in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises strugglingto overcome legal and institutional hurdles thatmake it difficult prevent <strong>for</strong> businesses to becomeor stay <strong>for</strong>mal. These are some of <strong>the</strong> broad219


3.Business Rights:Unlocking Barriers/Constraints to EmpowerIn<strong>for</strong>mal EnterprisesThe adverse effects upon <strong>the</strong> poor of living undera system of unequal opportunities of representation,political voice and power tend to reproduce<strong>the</strong>mselves over time and across generations,setting into motion a classical poverty trap fromwhich relatively few can escape. In this chapter,<strong>the</strong> position is taken that promoting businessrights in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy could helpto unlock pent-up talents and energies among<strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor and create an efficient andinclusive private sector. The view is that a keyto improving <strong>the</strong> quality of life of <strong>the</strong> poor and<strong>the</strong> disadvantaged is <strong>the</strong> creation of an efficientprivate sector with a sound domestic macroenvironment, and replete with trade policies, institutionalfoundations and adequate capacity tomaximise benefits within a broader macro globalenvironment. Such a creation would dependupon good economic governance, en<strong>for</strong>ceablelaws and regulations, effective institutions, practicesand dedicated people to support inclusiveand equitable development of <strong>the</strong> domesticprivate sector.This chapter <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e argues <strong>for</strong> effective andenabling environments, a regulatory regime,commercial law and good economic governance.It is expected that this process will empower <strong>the</strong>poor to use law and legal tools to prevail overpoverty, while persuading government to equitablyen<strong>for</strong>ce policies and regulations. This wouldrein<strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> role of <strong>the</strong> civil society in implementinggreater accountability of all actors andat all levels. Sound economic governance is builtupon principles of equity and equality of opportunities.With public policies and supportingaction, assurances could be given about accessto and distribution of assets, economic opportunities,and political voice participation in decisionmaking— all of which can help to promote <strong>the</strong>creation of sustainable enterprises. This is <strong>the</strong>path to address <strong>the</strong> often-heard demands to ‘level<strong>the</strong> playing field.’It is <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e essential to build upon and refine<strong>the</strong> above issues in <strong>the</strong> context of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong> of <strong>the</strong>Commission and re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> development agendaby broadening <strong>the</strong> discussion of business rightsand <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy in a comprehensivemanner that goes beyond <strong>for</strong>malisation per se.In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment of <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal business can generate sustainable livelihoodsonly by first addressing <strong>the</strong> constraints andbarriers that stifle <strong>the</strong>ir productive potential andencourage <strong>the</strong>m to have a voice in all aspects ofpolicy making, implementing and en<strong>for</strong>cing andhave <strong>the</strong> ability to w<strong>ork</strong> with governments ando<strong>the</strong>r stakeholders to create new rights, capacities,and opportunities.The core set of legal en<strong>for</strong>cement componentsare presented in Box 2, below.Empowerment has to be specific to context,<strong>the</strong> social reality of different groups, locationetc. Policymakers and practitioners must tailor<strong>the</strong> various elements from <strong>the</strong> framew<strong>ork</strong> to meetlocal circumstances. The example, below, demonstrateshow LE could address <strong>the</strong> specific conditionsof street vendors.Different levels of commercial rights are appropriateto <strong>the</strong> circumstances of different typesof in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses: notably, street vendors,in<strong>for</strong>mal manufacturers, in<strong>for</strong>mal transport providers,and small farmers. Commercial rights <strong>for</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses can be stratified as follows:• Basic commercial rights: right to w<strong>ork</strong>, in-220


Box 2 Unlocking Barriers: Legal Mechanisms to Empower In<strong>for</strong>malBusinesses1) Legal and bureaucratic procedures that allow in<strong>for</strong>maloperators or businesses to operate:• Simplifi ed registration procedures;• Simplifi ed licensing and permit procedures;• Identifi cation devices, including: ID cards <strong>for</strong> individualoperators, and business identification;• Legislation — e.g., municipal by-laws — that allowstreet vendors to operate in public spaces.2) Appropriate legal framew<strong>ork</strong>s that enshrine <strong>the</strong> followingas economic rights:• Access to finance, raw material, and productmarkets at fair prices ;• Access to transport and communication infrastructure;• Access to improved skills and technology;• Access to business development services;• Access to business incentive and trade promotionpackages: tax deferrals, subsidies, trade fairs.3) Legal property rights:• Private land;• Intellectual property.4) Use rights to public resources and appropriatezoning regulations:• Use rights to urban public land;• Use to common and public resources: pastures,<strong>for</strong>ests, and waterways;• appropriate zoning regulations where governing andunder what conditions in<strong>for</strong>mal operators or businessescan operate in central business districts,suburban areas, and/or industrial zones.5) Appropriate legal framew<strong>ork</strong>s and standards <strong>for</strong>what in<strong>for</strong>mal operators and businesses are allowed tobuy and sell:• Appropriate laws and regulations regarding whatare legal vs. illegal goods and services;• Appropriate product and process standards: <strong>for</strong>example, public health and sanitation concerns restreet food;• Marketing licenses <strong>for</strong> products and services.6) Appropriate legal tools to govern <strong>the</strong> transactionand contractual relationships of in<strong>for</strong>mal operators orbusinesses including:• Bargaining and negotiating mechanisms/power;• Legal and en<strong>for</strong>ceable contracts;• Grievance mechanisms;• Conflict resolution mechanisms;• Possibility of issuing shares, right to issue shares;• Right to advertise and protect brands and trademarks.7) Legal rights and mechanisms to provide in<strong>for</strong>maloperators and businesses with <strong>the</strong> following:• Temporary unemployment relief;• Insurance of various kinds, including of land, house,equipment, and o<strong>the</strong>r means of production;• Bankruptcy rules and default rules;• Limited liability, asset and capital protection;• Capital withdrawal and transfer rules.8) Legal right <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal operators and businessesto join or <strong>for</strong>m organisations, legal recognition of suchand legal right of <strong>the</strong> organisations to be representedin relevant policymaking and rule-setting institutions• Membership in mainstream business associations;• Membership in guilds or o<strong>the</strong>r associations ofsimilar types of entrepreneurs;• Representation in relevant planning andrule-setting bodies.221


Street VendorsCommon issues and challenges faceInsecure place of w<strong>ork</strong> due to competition <strong>for</strong> urban space.Capital on unfair terms due to dependence on wholesale tradersUncertain quantity, quality, and price of goods due to dependenceon wholesale traders.Lack of infrastructure i.e. shelter, water, sanitation.Ambiguous legal status leading to harassment.Evictions and bribes.Negative public image.What Legal Empowerment can do <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>mSecure vending sites.Provide access to capital on fair terms: a loan producttailored to <strong>the</strong>ir daily need <strong>for</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing capital.Boost bargaining power with wholesale traders.Infrastructure services at vending sites i.e. shelter,water, sanitation.Licence to sell issue identity cards.Freedom from harassment, evictions, and bribes.Positive public image.cluding right to vend; right to a w<strong>ork</strong> space• Intermediary commercial rights: right togovernment incentives and support includingprocurement and <strong>the</strong> right to publicinfrastructure• Advanced commercial rights: those that arerelevant <strong>for</strong> larger, more advanced in<strong>for</strong>malenterprises.These rights would <strong>the</strong>n apply in different ways todifferent types of street vendors including:• Those who sell fruit and vegetables: <strong>the</strong>yneed basic and intermediate commercialrights;• Those who sell cooked food: <strong>the</strong>y need basiccommercial rights and intermediate commercialrights but also need to be regulated<strong>for</strong> public safety concerns;• Those who sell small domestically-producedmanufactured goods need basic and intermediatecommercial rights and may alsoneed to be regulated to ensure <strong>the</strong> goods arenot pirated;• Those who sell more valuable imported manufacturedgoods need basic and intermediatecommercial rights and may also need tobe regulated to ensure that <strong>the</strong> goods arenot smuggled or pirated.The illustrations shown above would suggestconcerns about advanced commercial rights areessentially relevant only after <strong>the</strong> basic and intermediatecommercial rights are taken care of.Barriers and Constraints to BusinessRightsAddressing <strong>the</strong> issue of legally empoweringin<strong>for</strong>mal businesses is critical to unlocking <strong>the</strong>productive potential of individuals, communitiesand countries. There are significant barriers tobasic business rights, including <strong>the</strong> cost of, anddifficulty with repsect to accessing and obtaininglicenses or permits, <strong>the</strong> cost of <strong>for</strong>ming legalentities or, in some countries, even of registeringas a person engaged in commerce. And, and ofcourse, <strong>the</strong>re is also <strong>the</strong> weight of taxation.Cost-benefit analysis is influenced also by non-legalcosts. For example, if business people do nothave <strong>the</strong>ir basic human rights respected, <strong>the</strong> costof doing business rises. If <strong>the</strong> level of educationmakes counting difficult, that is a cost. If <strong>the</strong> levelof healthcare prevents people from using <strong>the</strong>irhuman capital, that, too is a cost. And outside <strong>the</strong>classic human rights rubric, if public transporta-222


tion is inadequate or <strong>the</strong> roads are largely impassable,that too is an additional cost. And all <strong>the</strong>secosts are effective barriers to exit from <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy, because <strong>the</strong>y make all o<strong>the</strong>r costs,including legal costs, that much more onerous.Below is an elaboration of implications <strong>for</strong> thosecurrently doing business in<strong>for</strong>mally.Legal, Regulatory, and AdministrativeBarriersRegulatory barriers comprise inappropriate orrigid requirements and stem from a governmentpolicymaking environment that normally wishesto have a total control ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong> a political or socio-economicagenda. Many developing countriesare emerging from a history of heavy-handedregulation, with approvals required <strong>for</strong> even <strong>the</strong>smallest activity, and authority overly centralisedand inflexible. This means <strong>the</strong>y are hampered by<strong>the</strong> legacy of a heavily regulated economy and acommand and control approach to administrationand en<strong>for</strong>cement. Poor quality law-making over<strong>the</strong> years has created a tangle of complex andinconsistent laws that present a daunting regulatoryhurdle to <strong>the</strong> would-be <strong>for</strong>mal enterprise. Assuch, <strong>the</strong> regulatory systems of <strong>the</strong>se countriesare not well developed to support a flourishingmarket economy that will create growth and<strong>for</strong>mal jobs. A study 56 carried out in 2002 foundthat <strong>the</strong> costs and barriers imposed by regulationin developing countries are not only higherthan <strong>the</strong>y were in <strong>the</strong> developed world when itembarked on industrialisation, but are higher insome cases than in <strong>the</strong> advanced countries today.Taking business entry costs as a proxy <strong>for</strong> allregulatory costs, <strong>the</strong> report suggested that <strong>the</strong>secosts in Africa (94%), in relation to GDP percapita, are much higher than those in o<strong>the</strong>r partsof <strong>the</strong> world — Central Europe (67%), IndustrialSouth Asia (19.80%), and <strong>for</strong> many advancedcountries (3%).The World Bank study on doing business usingindicators such as those in FIgure 3, 57 establishedclearly <strong>the</strong> correlation between <strong>the</strong> ease of doingbusiness and <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.Two methods were used to produce <strong>the</strong> ranking —one involved averaging out a country’s per<strong>for</strong>manceacross <strong>the</strong> indicators, and <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r used <strong>the</strong> rawvalues of indicators. Both regressions showed that<strong>the</strong>re is a statistically significant correlation betweena country’s overall per<strong>for</strong>mance on <strong>the</strong> DoingBusiness indicators and <strong>the</strong> size of its in<strong>for</strong>malFigure 3 Regulatory Burdens Impacting on In<strong>for</strong>mal Enterprises (World Bank, 2005)Starting a BusinessNumber of ProceduresTime (days)CostMinimum CapitalRegistering PropertyNumber of ProceduresTimeCostHiring and Firing of W<strong>ork</strong>ersDiffi culty of hiringRigidity of hoursDiffi culty of fi ringRigidity of employmentFiring costsGetting CreditCost to create collateralLegal rights of borrowers and lendersCredit in<strong>for</strong>mationPublic registry coveragePrivate bureau coverage223


Box 3 Most Difficult Places toDo Business(by specific category)Starting a Business• 17 Procedures in Uganda/Paraguay,• 694 days in Suriname• 1,194 percent of income per capita required as costin Sierra Leon• 4,233 percent of income per capita minimum capitalrequired in SyriaDealing with Licenses• 186 Procedures in Egypt• 668 days in Iran• 5,869 percent of income per capita required as costin MontenegroRegistering Property• 16 Procedures in Nigeria• 683 days in Haiti• 28 percent of property value as cost in SyriaEmploying W<strong>ork</strong>ers• On diffi culty of hiring index (100=worst) in Morocco,Nigeria and Tanzania• On diffi culty of fi ring index (100=worst) in Boliviaand Egypt• 329 weeks of salary as fi ring cost in Sierra LeoneTrading Across Borders• 16 number of documents required to export inZambia• 20 number of documents required to import inRwandaGetting Credits• 0 Strength of legal rights in Cambodia, from an Index0-10 (0 is <strong>the</strong> worst)• 0 Depth of credit in<strong>for</strong>mation in 48 countries, froman Index 0-10 (0 is <strong>the</strong> worst)Paying Taxes• 130 times payment per year in Uzbekistan• 291 percent of profi t as total tax rate in GambiaClosing a Business• Takes up to 10 years in India• Cost (percent of estate): 76 in Lao PDRSource: World Bank: Doing Business 2007(prepared by Mahmood Iqbal)economy; a worse environment <strong>for</strong> doing businesscorrelates with a larger in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Theanalysis also examined <strong>the</strong> relationship between<strong>the</strong> individual measures of ease of doing businessand <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.The World Bank has conducted a comprehensivestudy, 58 in identifying and quantifying<strong>the</strong> cost of barriers <strong>for</strong> all regions of <strong>the</strong> worldand individual countries. The extreme cases aresummarissed in Box 3.The World Bank study also shows that regulatoryenvironment and in<strong>for</strong>mality are highly correlated:<strong>the</strong> greater <strong>the</strong> difficulty in business operation,<strong>the</strong> larger <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector. In o<strong>the</strong>rwords, barriers or extent of difficulties in doingbusiness <strong>for</strong>ce many operators to take <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malroute.Administrative barriers are <strong>the</strong> bureaucraticrequirements that flow from regulations, <strong>the</strong>ir implementationand en<strong>for</strong>cement. A regulation maybe well-designed, proportionate and efficient, butits true effect on enterprises comes from <strong>the</strong> wayin which it is administered. Administrative barriersare <strong>the</strong> hassle that dissuades in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprisesfrom wanting to interact with governmentofficials; 59 <strong>the</strong>y include excessive paperw<strong>ork</strong>; civilservice inefficiency leading to delays in decision-making;low levels of civil service capacity,i.e. poor skills levels so that mistakes are made,and too few people and access points providingservices; inaccessibility, as when <strong>the</strong>re is too littledelegation to <strong>the</strong> front-line and decisions have tobe referred up to <strong>the</strong> management chain; generalbureaucratic obstruction (perhaps stemming frominherent distrust of <strong>the</strong> private sector by officials)contributing to delays, and abuse of position(linked to corruption).The time and money spent complying with governmentregulations impose significant transac-224


Figure 4 Regulatory Environment and In<strong>for</strong>malityGreater ease of doing business is associated with less <strong>for</strong>malityIn<strong>for</strong>mal sector (share of GDP)HigherImplied cut in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector from improving to<strong>the</strong> top on ease of doing business40%30%20%}Implied cutImpliedshare aftercutLower10%Least difficultMost difficultCountries ranked by ease of doing business, quintilesLeast difficultNote: Relationships are significant at 1% level and remain significant when controlling <strong>for</strong> income per capita.Source: World Bank (2005)Most difficulttion costs on businesses. In addition, <strong>the</strong> directcost of payments, such as licensing fees, alsorepresents a significant cost of doing business.Conversely, payments made to avoid detectionof non-compliance, or payoffs to government officialsare <strong>the</strong> costs of operating in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malsector. The regulations imposed on business fallinto several categories. Some regulations governingbusiness start-up raise <strong>the</strong> costs of entering<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal sector, o<strong>the</strong>rs govern ongoing businessactivity, and additional regulations are dictated by<strong>the</strong> central authority or by regional or municipalgovernments. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, small businesses facegovernment-imposed costs in <strong>the</strong> areas of labourpractices, payroll charges, health and safety standards,taxation, and <strong>for</strong>eign trade.Governance Issues: In many developing countries,corruption and rent-seeking reduce in<strong>for</strong>mationflows and weaken contract en<strong>for</strong>cement, reducingeconomic activity, especially <strong>for</strong>eign investment.Every major study on barriers to <strong>for</strong>malisation andindeed on barriers to growth generally, refers to<strong>the</strong> problem of corruption.Often it is not <strong>the</strong> financial cost itself thatcreates <strong>the</strong> largest transaction cost obstacleto setting up a small business, but ra<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>time and energy required to navigate <strong>the</strong> bureaucraticmaze, along with <strong>the</strong> opportunity costsinvolved. A well-known example was provided byHernando de Soto when he measured <strong>the</strong> cost ofestablishing a small garment manufacturing enterprisein Lima, Peru. He found that it requiredmany different steps over an extended periodof time to set up a small <strong>for</strong>mal manufacturingcompany. 60 Although Peru has substantially re<strong>for</strong>medand simplified <strong>the</strong> process of setting upa small business, de Soto’s overall conclusionsremain as valid <strong>for</strong> many o<strong>the</strong>r Latin Americancountries today as <strong>the</strong>y did in Peru in <strong>the</strong> late1980s. This is why entrepreneurs frequentlyresort to bribes or professional ‘fixers’ in order toexpedite <strong>the</strong> registration and licensing process.Fixers’ fees to establish a company range fromUS$600 to US$800 to establish a company inmost Latin American countries; <strong>the</strong>y rise quitesharply as <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> firm increases.225


Case Study:Ukraine and Private Business DevelopmentThe dimension of <strong>the</strong> problem: A 1999 surveyof businesses and households suggested that,<strong>the</strong>re were 3.073 million businesses in Ukraine,of which 2.651 million (86%) had no employees.Comparing <strong>the</strong> official figures of smallfirms (with fewer than 50 employees) suggestedthat over 80 percent of <strong>the</strong>se 2.651 million, ortwo million businesses were unregistered andin<strong>for</strong>mal, which is, strictly speaking,, illegal, inUkrainian terms.Key problem: Corruption and o<strong>the</strong>r rent-seekingbehaviour. It is widely agreed that <strong>the</strong> biggestissue <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> regulatory environment <strong>for</strong> Ukrainianbusinesses is its unpredictability. Regulationsare often confusing or unclear, many regulatoryactivities lack a comprehensive legislativebasis, in<strong>for</strong>mation is lacking and procedures areunnecessarily complex. Rules change frequently— <strong>for</strong> example <strong>the</strong>re were 34 amendments tokey tax laws in 2004. The lack of clear and accuratein<strong>for</strong>mation <strong>for</strong> businesses on <strong>the</strong> currentstate of <strong>the</strong> law assists rent seeking behaviourby corrupt officials.Inspections are still <strong>the</strong> biggest problem facedby Ukrainian business, but <strong>the</strong> problem appearsto be decreasing slowly. In 2001, 94 percent offirms were inspected at some time during <strong>the</strong>year (a figure which had declined by 20 percentsince 2000) with <strong>the</strong> average firm receiving11.7 inspections. In 2004, 78 percent of firmssurveyed were inspected. The typical smallfirm spent 22 days dealing with inspections in2001, compared to 27 days in 2000. There isno comparable figure <strong>for</strong> 2004.In 2001, 40 percent of all firms surveyed madeunofficial payments to inspecting bodies, and28 percent in 2002. In 2004, this figure appearedto have dropped to 20 percent.Key problem remaining: Current legislativeframew<strong>ork</strong>s are too complex, confused andscattered. As a result of re<strong>for</strong>m and donor assistanceover several years, <strong>the</strong> 140 steps thatbusinesses had to take <strong>for</strong> full registration havenow been decreased to 70. Needless to say, thisnumber still is very high.(Source: A Review of <strong>the</strong> Development of <strong>the</strong> Private Sector in Ukrainesince1998, and an Evaluation of <strong>the</strong> Contribution of DFID. DFID 2006)Corruption deters <strong>for</strong>malisation as businesses stayoff registries and tax rolls in order to minimisecontact with corrupt public officials. One broadstudy of 69 countries found a direct link betweendecreasing corruption and an increasing <strong>for</strong>maleconomy. 61 In a study of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector inUkraine, 82 percent of businesses believed thatbribes to officials were necessary in order to continueto operate. 62 The smallest businesses suffermost from paying bribes, because <strong>the</strong>se sumsdecrease <strong>the</strong> paltry profits made by thm.Financial Barriers: Financial institutions dependon <strong>the</strong> credibility of <strong>for</strong>mal documentation toprovide <strong>the</strong> security and en<strong>for</strong>ceability necessaryto extend credit. As in<strong>for</strong>mal businessescommonly do not possess land title or a standingrelationship with a bank, <strong>the</strong> most prevalent<strong>for</strong>ms of loan guarantee, real estate and fiduciarycollateral, are generally unavailable. Formallenders typically require borrowers to providefinancial statements and credible documentationrelated to <strong>the</strong> lender’s recent operations (bank226


statements, invoices, etc.). Accordingly, in<strong>for</strong>malentrepreneurs unaccustomed to separating <strong>the</strong>irbusiness and personal transactions or recordingand maintaining <strong>the</strong> firm’s in<strong>for</strong>mation, or whouse in<strong>for</strong>mal suppliers who are unable to providedocumentation as solicited by <strong>the</strong> lender, will berequired to make significant adjustments to <strong>the</strong>irdaily operations.The greater <strong>the</strong> exposure to risk that a bankinginstitution assumes due to lack of credible documentationor an unreliable legal framew<strong>ork</strong>, <strong>the</strong>more it needs to charge higher interest rates andguarantees to loan ratio requirements. Thus, inmany developing countries, bank loan portfoliosare often over-collateralised (guarantees to loanratios of greater than one), which fur<strong>the</strong>r limitscredit access. In Honduras, creditors ask <strong>for</strong> aguarantee of 150 percent of <strong>the</strong> value of a loan.The low access to credit in <strong>the</strong> developing worldalso relates to limited competition in <strong>the</strong> financialservices industries of many countries and <strong>the</strong>state’s imposition of high licensing requirementson financial intermediaries. There are also fundamentalproblems of scale in lending that do notfavour those with meagre assets.Innovative lending schemes such as <strong>the</strong> grouplendingschemes pioneered by <strong>the</strong> Grameen Bank,BRAC 63 in Bangladesh, and NGOs in some o<strong>the</strong>rcountries, have been able to somewhat circumvent<strong>the</strong> problem of limited access of <strong>the</strong> poor tocollateral. By tying each group member’s abilityto receive loans to <strong>the</strong> repayment of o<strong>the</strong>r members(i.e., one member’s failure to make a loanpayment results in <strong>the</strong> loss of credit <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rmembers), loans are essentially secured by peerpressure. However, such lending schemes shouldnot be considered a replacement <strong>for</strong> traditionalcredit providers, as <strong>the</strong>ir small lending portfolios,often prohibitively high interest rates, and relianceon external funding limit <strong>the</strong> potential reach.Costs of In<strong>for</strong>malityThe barriers discussed above clearly establish<strong>the</strong> reasons why <strong>the</strong> poor opt to remain inin<strong>for</strong>mal businesses. In<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises oftenhave limited access to broader economic opportunitiesand are especially vulnerable to <strong>the</strong> uncertainties,<strong>the</strong> corruption and even violence prevalentoutside <strong>the</strong> rule of law and have few meansto settle disputes apart from bribery or violence.Without legal rights or protection, <strong>the</strong>y are in acontinual state of legal and political vulnerability.Small in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses assume larger risks(than <strong>the</strong> larger and usually <strong>for</strong>mal firms) andspend more time and resources to monitor <strong>the</strong>iragents and partners (which explains why <strong>the</strong>yusually hire relatives and close friends). Theychoose low-risk businesses that often yield lowreturns. They operate with a limited amount ofcapital and as a result, <strong>the</strong>y are <strong>for</strong>ced to dobusiness at a very small scale. Since <strong>the</strong>y hardlyaccumulate capital, it is very difficult to leaveor sell <strong>the</strong> business to pass on benefits of bothtangible and intangible assets. 64The relationship between poverty, in<strong>for</strong>mality andpolitical alienation leaves <strong>the</strong> poor especially vulnerableto organised crime and o<strong>the</strong>r unscrupulousparties that rise up to fill <strong>the</strong> gaps. <strong>Making</strong> <strong>for</strong>malitymore accessible could legally empower <strong>the</strong> poorto grow <strong>the</strong>ir businesses, enjoy <strong>the</strong> appreciation of<strong>the</strong>ir assets in <strong>for</strong>mal property markets, and accesscredit more easily. This is <strong>the</strong> vision of <strong>the</strong> Commissionas a means to alleviate poverty. 65The benefits that a business person would obtainby going into <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy, would be thatregistration of ownership rights in property wouldmean having capital to collateralise; <strong>the</strong>re couldbe state support <strong>for</strong> collection of obligations;greater ease and record of transactions and hopefully,increased protection <strong>for</strong> intellectual property227


The Chart below captures broadly <strong>the</strong> costs and benefits to businesses of being <strong>for</strong>mal versus in<strong>for</strong>mal.INFORM<strong>AL</strong>ITYCostsFewer mechanisms <strong>for</strong> dealing with risk and uncertaintyBribe and CorruptionLack of identityLimited access to economies of scale and scope (markets are limited to family circles)Impossibility of diversifying risks and investmentsHigher transport costsRisk of losing family assets, unlimited liabilityLess access to market knowledgeDiffi culty to establish business hierarchies different from <strong>the</strong> family onesDiffi culty to divide and specialize labourEn<strong>for</strong>cing contracts only by <strong>for</strong>ceLimited Access to capitalShort-term fi rms and investmentLosing <strong>the</strong> advantages of advertising because <strong>the</strong>y have to hide <strong>the</strong>ir businessUnpredictability (inspections, laws, etc)Higher credit costsBenefitsAvoiding <strong>the</strong> costs of<strong>for</strong>mality (taxes, permits,regulations)FORM<strong>AL</strong>ITYCostsAdministrative PermitsTaxesProduct RegulationsLabour Regulations228BenefitsLimited LiabilityShielding <strong>the</strong> fi rms from shareholders & creditorsEn<strong>for</strong>ceable rules and agreements among partners Predictable rules to withdraw capitalfrom <strong>the</strong> fi rmThe possibility of issuing shares that facilitate <strong>the</strong> perpetual succession of <strong>the</strong> firm, canbe used to raise capital, transmit info about <strong>the</strong> business and represent rights over <strong>the</strong>enterpriseAccess to business identification mechanisms that transmit in<strong>for</strong>mation about <strong>the</strong> nationalidentity, address, <strong>the</strong> assets <strong>the</strong>y own, <strong>the</strong>ir financial history, etc.Access to rules that establish en<strong>for</strong>ceable standards of responsibility among partners,administrators and w<strong>ork</strong>ers, allowing a more efficient division and specialization of labourand achieving economies of scaleEn<strong>for</strong>ceable contracts, Access to <strong>for</strong>mal conflict resolution mechanismsLegally advertise and protection of brands and trademarksPredictable and speedy rules <strong>for</strong> closing of business,Default rulesMembership of trade associationsPermits to use public land, resources and utilities.Access to incentives packages such as tax rebates, exports licenses and trade fairsFlexibility


ights. O<strong>the</strong>r benefits would include a potentiallylarger market, or at least easier access to largermarkets. Although business persons in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy routinely trade across borders, inAfrica, only <strong>the</strong> people in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal market areable to import or export through major ports or anyo<strong>the</strong>r major transit areas, given <strong>the</strong> presence ofcustoms and o<strong>the</strong>r border officials. A benefit of beingin <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal market, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, is <strong>the</strong> potentialto grow a larger business and to get out of poverty.As discussed in <strong>the</strong> next section, this costbenefitanalysis highlights <strong>the</strong> areas where<strong>the</strong> law can make <strong>the</strong> transition from <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malto <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economies easier. The role <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>law, <strong>the</strong>n, is to reduce <strong>the</strong> costs and enhance <strong>the</strong>benefits of entering <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy. Because<strong>the</strong> process may be long, and because <strong>the</strong>existence of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy is an adaptiveresponse ra<strong>the</strong>r than moral failure, <strong>the</strong> law shouldnot seek to <strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> poor out of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy by increasing costs or reducing benefits.The point is to empower <strong>the</strong> poor to leave <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy and to provide incentives <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong>m to choose to do so.Rights-based Legal EmpowermentMost people enter <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy not bychoice but out of a need to survive. The decentw<strong>ork</strong> deficits are most pronounced in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy, where <strong>the</strong> majority of in<strong>for</strong>mal businesseshave little or no social protection andreceive little or no social security. Poor respect<strong>for</strong>, or lack of freedom of association, make it difficult<strong>for</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ers and employers to organise in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. 66In 2001, an ILO Conference concluded thatin<strong>for</strong>mality is principally a governance issue and itencouraged employers’ and w<strong>ork</strong>ers’ organisationsto extend <strong>the</strong>ir representation throughout <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy. The growth of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economycan often be traced to inappropriate, ineffective,misguided or badly implemented macroeconomicand social policies, often developed withouttripartite consultations among w<strong>ork</strong>ers, employersand governments. W<strong>ork</strong>ers’ representatives on <strong>the</strong>committee <strong>for</strong>cefully stressed that in<strong>for</strong>mality isnot a solution to unemployment and <strong>the</strong> resultingreport called on governments to provide conducivemacroeconomic, social, legal and political framew<strong>ork</strong>s<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> large-scale creation of sustainable,decent jobs and business opportunities.However a fundamental concern in <strong>the</strong> recognitionof rights is <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> individual legalidentity, as expressed by M. Woolcock: 67To <strong>the</strong> extent <strong>the</strong>re is now a broad scholarly andpolicy consensus on <strong>the</strong> importance of propertyrights <strong>for</strong> development — i.e., <strong>for</strong> encouraginginvestment by <strong>the</strong> poor (and o<strong>the</strong>rs) insmall business ventures; or, concomitantly, arecognition that endemic corruption, costlybureaucratic delays and weak contract en<strong>for</strong>cementall undermine capacities and incentives tomake such investments — it is also importantto appreciate that responding effectively to<strong>the</strong>se concerns is not simply (or only) a matterof encouraging policymakers to ‘grant’ propertyrights, ‘stamp out corruption’ or make relevantline ministries ‘more efficient.’ In <strong>the</strong> mostelementary sense, property rights must be givento actual people, who <strong>the</strong>mselves — in order toadvance and defend <strong>the</strong>ir personal status andidentity. A crucial prerequisite, <strong>the</strong>n, to enhancing<strong>the</strong> quality of property rights is ensuring thatresidents/citizens have recognised documents(such as birth, death, marriage and divorcecertificates) verifying such basic in<strong>for</strong>mation as<strong>the</strong>ir name, age, sex and marital status.To balance between rights and market-basedapproaches, emphasis should be laid on programmesproviding increased wages, governmentassistance, education, land re<strong>for</strong>m, labour monitoring,and access to credit, which are good starts229


in helping <strong>the</strong> poor create wealth. However, institutionalre<strong>for</strong>m is needed to eradicate poverty, attaindevelopment, and successfully transition to freemarket economies. Re<strong>for</strong>ms that reduce bureaucraticred tape and bring <strong>the</strong> cost of legal complianceunder that of extra-legality are necessary to<strong>for</strong>malise those who were previously excluded.Such re<strong>for</strong>ms should also create greater regulatorytransparency, allow <strong>for</strong> citizen input, and aim atfighting corruption and inefficiency. When tailoredto local circumstances, titling programmes thatturn dead assets of <strong>the</strong> poor into useable capitalare great tools <strong>for</strong> poverty reduction, development,and attaining legal inclusion <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mals. 68To Sum UpThe constraints and barriers discussed in thischapter clearly establish <strong>the</strong> reasons why <strong>the</strong> pooropt to remain in in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses. In<strong>for</strong>malenterprises often have limited access to broadereconomic opportunities and are especiallyvulnerable to uncertainties, corruption and evenviolence which is prevalent outside <strong>the</strong> rule oflaw. They have few means to settle disputes apartfrom bribery or violence. Without legal rights orprotection, <strong>the</strong>y are in a continual state of legaland political vulnerability. Thus making <strong>for</strong>malitymore accessible could legally empower <strong>the</strong> poorto grow <strong>the</strong>ir businesses, enjoy <strong>the</strong> appreciationof <strong>the</strong>ir assets in <strong>for</strong>mal property markets, andaccess credit more easily. This is <strong>the</strong> vision of <strong>the</strong>Commission as a means to alleviate poverty whichhas been <strong>the</strong> focus of this as well as <strong>the</strong> followingsection which highlights <strong>the</strong> importance of accessto markets, goods and services and infrastructure.4. Empowering In<strong>for</strong>malEnterprises through accessto markets, goods andservices, and infrastructureImproving <strong>the</strong> functioning of marketsThe close correlation between being poor andoperating in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy in <strong>the</strong> ruraland <strong>the</strong> urban sectors is conspicuous. Also, highbusiness costs and <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy movein parallel in response to ill-designed, unstableand non-participatory rules and regulations, lackof secure property rights, inadequate governmentcapacity and resources to en<strong>for</strong>ce laws and regulations,a lack of transparency, accountability andautonomy of judicial process as well as high degreeof macroeconomic instability and corruption.Inadequate access to markets, and poor quality ornon-existent basic public services and infrastructurefur<strong>the</strong>r lead to low productivity, particularly<strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses.Agriculture accounts <strong>for</strong> a large share of grossdomestic product (GDP) and employment inSub-Saharan Africa. It is primarily a family activity,a component of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy with <strong>the</strong>majority of farmers being small holders owningbetween 0.5 and 2.0 hectares. Women providenearly 50 percent of <strong>the</strong> labour <strong>for</strong>ce and producemost of <strong>the</strong> food crops <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> family. The recentreview by <strong>the</strong> Independent Evaluation Group of<strong>the</strong> World Bank assistance to agriculture in Sub-Saharan Africa makes a pressing case <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>necessity of access to credits and markets, roads,fertilisers, seeds, water, etc. by <strong>the</strong> impoverishedfarmers to sustain <strong>the</strong>ir lives and livelihoods.Given that poor households are concentratedin agriculture, any improvement in <strong>the</strong>ir livelihoodswould necessitate entail in part in making230


agricultural activities more productive. Improvedaccess to markets and technology are <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>eimportant as is <strong>the</strong> need to streng<strong>the</strong>n propertyrights and create better methods of risk management.At <strong>the</strong> same time, well over half of <strong>the</strong> 1.1 billionpeople projected to join <strong>the</strong> world’s populationbetween now and 2030 may live in under-servicedslums 69 <strong>the</strong>reby raising <strong>the</strong> urban population,including those living in poverty, well abovethat of rural areas. Additionally, conflicts andnatural disasters are causing migration fromthose areas to developing countries with relativelygreater economic strength in order to seekout entrepreneurial and business opportunities.These migrants glide into <strong>the</strong> burgeoning in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy of <strong>the</strong> countries of destination and in<strong>the</strong> absence of inclusive development processes,<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy would continue to expand.Of <strong>the</strong> three billion urban dwellers today, onebillion live in ‘slums’ i.e. in areas where peoplelack access to key necessities such as potablewater, sanitation, basic energy services or durablehousing. 70 For <strong>the</strong> slum inhabitants, disease andviolence are threats faced on a daily basis andhealth care and education <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> children are adistant hope. As <strong>the</strong> pro poor growth re<strong>for</strong>m mustincrease <strong>the</strong> utilisation of <strong>the</strong> marketable assetsof <strong>the</strong> poor, it is vital to ensure that markets <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor are better integrated in to <strong>the</strong> economywith efficient backward and <strong>for</strong>ward linkages.Accordingly, targeted public investments needto be stepped up in education, healthcare,water and sanitation and energy services, andinfrastructure 71 <strong>for</strong> enabling entrepreneurship andgenerating sustainable livelihoods. Also publicinvestments are crucial <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> ‘private-basedeconomy’ to prosper and to allow <strong>the</strong> private sectorto create employment and sustain long termSustainable LivelihoodsFramew<strong>ork</strong>A livelihood is sustainable if it can recoverfrom stresses and shocks while maintainingor enhancing <strong>the</strong> necessary capabilities andassets. The interventions <strong>for</strong> engaging <strong>the</strong>private sector would reduce <strong>the</strong> vulnerabilityof <strong>the</strong> poor and increase <strong>the</strong>ir resiliencethrough investments in enhancing accessto resources, building assets <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>m, andimproving <strong>the</strong>ir skills and capabilities tosupport livelihood opportunities and designa living. Income generation is <strong>the</strong> foundationof a sustainable livelihood. Access to basicservices like energy, water and sanitation,housing and healthcare is fundamental to enablepeople to seek, maintain and continueto w<strong>ork</strong>. For a livelihood to be sustainable,it must lead to a surplus beyond immediateconsumption requirements to allow additionalresources <strong>for</strong> overcoming shocks andstresses, when required.economic growth. In <strong>the</strong> absence of adequateinfrastructure, health services, education, inclusivefinancial services, etc., market <strong>for</strong>ces alonecan accomplish little.However, <strong>the</strong>se basic and necessary services represent‘missing markets’ or ‘incomplete markets.’While <strong>the</strong> demand clearly exists, it is not communicatedthrough conventional market characteristicelements because of asymmetric in<strong>for</strong>mationand regulatory and transaction barriers to marketaccess and market creation <strong>for</strong> new productsand services. These, in turn limit <strong>the</strong> supply of<strong>the</strong>se goods and services. Additional supply-sideconstraints include <strong>the</strong> reluctance of <strong>the</strong> privatesector to invest in measuring <strong>the</strong> demand <strong>for</strong> newproducts and services because of new and rela-231


tively unknown markets that require innovativemarketing mechanisms including multi-stakeholderpartnerships.Increasing Access to Goods andServicesMarkets have to be created to target <strong>the</strong> groupsthat are currently excluded from <strong>the</strong>m. Forinstance, well focused and participatory policiescan lead to <strong>the</strong> evolution of markets <strong>for</strong> goodsand services through improvements in production,distribution and storage components of <strong>the</strong>value chain and mitigating <strong>the</strong> risk of starvation.As discussed earlier, lack of access to potablewater, basic sanitation, energy services, and solidwaste management services adversely affects <strong>the</strong>lives and livelihoods of poor people directly andhas a devastating impact on ef<strong>for</strong>ts to engagein trade and business. The poor pay many timesmore <strong>for</strong> water (of questionable quality) and o<strong>the</strong>ressential services than <strong>the</strong> rich. 72 While in <strong>the</strong>rich countries, public spending on health is nearlyUS$3000 per capita, <strong>the</strong> poorest countries canaf<strong>for</strong>d to devote barely US$10 per capita or soto public health per year. 73 At this level of investment,it is not possible to operate and manage aCase Study:New markets lead to new opportunities <strong>for</strong> rural in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses— VegCARE, KenyaLess than a year ago, Mutulu was living below<strong>the</strong> poverty line, along with three-quarters of <strong>the</strong>population of Makueni district in eastern Kenya.Now, he is one of more than 400 farmers sellingvegetables in supermarkets in <strong>the</strong> UK suchas Tesco and Sainsbury’s.‘Be<strong>for</strong>e, I cycled 10 km each day to sell myproduce to middle men and <strong>the</strong>y gave me lowprices and sometimes did not even buy myproduce.’ Now Mutulu educates his childrenand is saving money thanks to VegCARE — abusiness partnership that has helped over 400farmers gain access to markets and, on average,doubled <strong>the</strong>ir incomes in six months.Their baby corn is sold in Tesco and Sainsbury’sand <strong>the</strong>ir aubergines, chillies and okra aredestined <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> tables of <strong>the</strong> Asian communityin <strong>the</strong> UK.’When VegCARE came and said that<strong>the</strong>y would market our produce <strong>for</strong> us, mostpeople doubted <strong>the</strong>m. I was one of <strong>the</strong> first in<strong>the</strong> Kwa Kyai scheme, which now has over 300farmers who decided to join VegCARE.’The partnership’s roots are in a project, initiallypiloted by CARE, which showed that if smallholderswere given access to markets <strong>the</strong>y couldand were willing to invest in farming. The projectwas a success but not commercially viable,so CARE linked up with Vegpro, <strong>the</strong> third largestvegetable buyer and producer in <strong>the</strong> region .Asa result, Vegpro’s supply to <strong>the</strong> market fromsmallholder farmers increased as <strong>the</strong>ir incomesand livelihoods improved.Initially Vegpro bought <strong>the</strong> produce and did notget involved in production. CARE pre-financed<strong>the</strong> production and provided technical supportto <strong>the</strong> farmers. Now a rural enterprise, knownas VegCARE, has been <strong>for</strong>med to take over <strong>the</strong>activities. It is a new type of partnership, bornout of an aid project that was aimed at helpingfarming communities in <strong>the</strong> long term — andgiving <strong>the</strong>m ways of making a sustainable living<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>mselves, <strong>the</strong>ir families and <strong>the</strong>ir communities.Source: CARE Canada, 2007232


primary health system. Similarly, it is estimatedthat achieving <strong>the</strong> Millennium Development Goals<strong>for</strong> water and sanitation would requires additionalannual funding of US$10 - US$25billion; an estimatedUS$700 billion of investment is required tobring electricity to an additional 1.4 billion people.There is need across much of this world <strong>for</strong>greater resources to effectively deliver basicservices to <strong>the</strong> poor. While increased financingis a necessary condition, it is not sufficient toensure that <strong>the</strong> unmet needs of <strong>the</strong> poor and <strong>the</strong>vulnerable are fulfilled. In <strong>the</strong> case of educationand health services, lessons learnt from a numberof developing countries have shown that increaseof funding in any given sector does not alwayslead to delivery of enhanced access and improvedquality of service. Increasing public expendituresmay not lead to anticipated outcomes if <strong>the</strong> institutionsand professionals responsible <strong>for</strong> deliveryof integrated services have inadequate capacityand are not accountable. Accordingly, capacitydevelopment, participation, transparency and accountabilityare mandatory to ensuring that fundsallocated to public service <strong>for</strong> equitable developmentreach <strong>the</strong>ir intended targets.Investments in health, education and basic services,like energy, water and sanitation, involveincreasingly both <strong>the</strong> public and private sectors.In many countries, such services are in part beingdelivered through private initiatives that includecooperatives, communities and independentnetw<strong>ork</strong> providers. This in turn has given rise toexperimentation with privatisation of core functionsof <strong>the</strong> state (services delivery, <strong>for</strong> example)and increasing participation of delivery throughoperators in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Privatisationhas not yielded many positive results as itreduces <strong>the</strong> ability of <strong>the</strong> state to define an activesocial and economic agenda. In<strong>for</strong>mal operatorsrequire regulation as well as capacity development,particularly <strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> perspective of qualitycontrol and also <strong>for</strong> consumer protection.But, since <strong>the</strong> poor interact with <strong>the</strong> privatesector, both as consumers and entrepreneurs,<strong>the</strong> private sector can play an important role indelivering goods and services <strong>for</strong> developmentand poverty alleviation. This would w<strong>ork</strong> best inpartnerships that also include civil society organisations,because <strong>the</strong>y are vital in assuring <strong>the</strong>participatory and accountable approaches needed<strong>for</strong> improving <strong>the</strong> quality of life of <strong>the</strong> poor.At <strong>the</strong> same time, governments are increasinglyrecognising <strong>the</strong> benefits of decentralisation inmaking <strong>the</strong> delivery of services more effective.For local communities to take advantage of <strong>the</strong>benefits of decentralization, it is critical to putinstitutions in place <strong>for</strong> en<strong>for</strong>cing accountability,reducing costs of varying kinds (<strong>for</strong> transactions,negotiations and en<strong>for</strong>cement of contracts), and<strong>for</strong> developing adequate capacity to facilitatecoordination among public agencies, private enterprises,NGOs, and civil society organisations.Multi-stakeholder partnerships in public servicedelivery involving state and non-state actors cancontribute to mobilising <strong>the</strong>ir competitive advantagein terms of capacity and resources from variouspartners and supplementing traditional directpublic delivery of services.Well-trained and motivated service providers,whe<strong>the</strong>r from public, private, or civil societycommunities, and adequate institutions withtransparent procedures and responsive accountabilitysystems, are important constituents ofeffective public service delivery. Involvement of<strong>the</strong> poor <strong>the</strong>mselves in setting service deliverypriorities, infrastructure investment planning,level of service and oversight, responsive feedbackmechanisms, and accountability, is criticalin determining <strong>the</strong> quality of service provided.233


Case Study:Linking Markets: Promoting sustainable tourism development with indigenousand rural communities in Latin AmericaAiming at supporting grass-roots initiatives andsmall and community based enterprises consolidationin <strong>the</strong> tourism sector, <strong>the</strong> ILO has beensupporting a programme in Latin America, <strong>the</strong>main purpose of which is to assist rural andindigenous communities usually engaged inw<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, to gain greateraccess to new markets and business developmentservices.Operating since 2000, REDTURS is nowpresent in seven Latin American countries; itrelies on a netw<strong>ork</strong> of communities, institutions,and resources devoted to encouraging <strong>the</strong>development of sustainable tourism keeping inmind economic productivity, social equity andcultural identity. REDTURS has encouraged <strong>the</strong>competitive advantages of <strong>the</strong>se communitiesin fostering quality job creation and productivityincreases mainly through three strategies: a)improving <strong>the</strong> service supplied by making <strong>the</strong>most out of existing social capital and training<strong>the</strong> community’s labour <strong>for</strong>ce; b) gaining marketshares by applying a five-point marketing strategy;and c) establishing strategic cooperativealliances involving o<strong>the</strong>r netw<strong>ork</strong>s and internationalagencies. By promoting participatorymechanisms <strong>for</strong> dialogue and capacity building<strong>for</strong> local partners, REDTURS supported <strong>the</strong>creation of four national community tourismnetw<strong>ork</strong>s that have benefited several indigenouscommunities. Source: ILOThe provision of efficient, reliable and af<strong>for</strong>dablepublic infrastructure services should w<strong>ork</strong> as acatalytic incentive encouraging enterprises in<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy to move upwards along <strong>the</strong>continuum towards greater <strong>for</strong>malisation.Inclusive financial servicesLimited access to w<strong>ork</strong>ing capital and financialservices including risk management services isresponsible <strong>for</strong> holding back <strong>the</strong> growth potentialof in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises. Micro-entrepreneurs in<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy regard <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> financeas a top priority. The ILO’s Global Agenda <strong>for</strong>Employment identifies <strong>the</strong> constraints on <strong>the</strong>development and growth of efficient and competitiveenterprises as ‘a wide swath of policy areasparticularly those arising from difficult accessto credit and o<strong>the</strong>r financial markets.’ 74 Financecan be a dominant tool to initiate and rein<strong>for</strong>ceself organisation among those in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy. It is often <strong>the</strong> monetary transactionsthat catalyse <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mation of joint liability andsolidarity groups, some of which develop multipurposeself-help organisations.Access to finance is essential <strong>for</strong> creating anenterprise and keeping it going. A considerableexpansion of rural bank branches in India promotednon-agricultural output and enhanced economicgrowth. Additionally, <strong>the</strong> expansion of bankbranches led, indirectly, to an increase in agriculturalwages and reduction of rural poverty. 75But, it is often <strong>the</strong> case that access to credit inconjunction with macroeconomic policies relatingto trade, may w<strong>ork</strong> to fur<strong>the</strong>r streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>the</strong> larger enterprises while preventing smallerones from gaining access to global markets. Forinstance, export promotion policies favouring <strong>the</strong>coir industry in Sri Lanka directed a shift in <strong>the</strong>supply of coconut husks to mechanised units234


(owned by men with access to credit), and awayfrom manual units owned by women who hadlittle access to credit. 76While <strong>the</strong> availability of credit is a concern, what isequally important are <strong>the</strong> terms on which it is availableand whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y are within <strong>the</strong> reach of <strong>the</strong>existing and potential entrepreneurs. Most micro,small and medium enterprises need small loansand small-scale deals that banks, in general, areei<strong>the</strong>r unable or sometimes unwilling to provide.At <strong>the</strong> same time, self-employed w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal sector do not have collateral to offer as aguarantee. Most operators in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy<strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e look to in<strong>for</strong>mal financial sources.Micro-finance‘The poor are bankable’ is <strong>the</strong> important lessonwe have learnt after nearly three decades ofCase Study:Alternate Model of In<strong>for</strong>mal Credit: SMEs Helping In<strong>for</strong>mal Enterprises in PeruVincent Sanchez lives in <strong>the</strong> community ofSan Martin de Porres, with his wife, Ruth, and<strong>the</strong>ir two kids. This is a semi-<strong>for</strong>mal settlement,where an association, ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> city ofLima, provides electricity and water. Vincent has15-years experience in <strong>the</strong> metal w<strong>ork</strong>ing businessand lives in San Martin de Porres whichmeans he is not able to qualify <strong>for</strong> a loan from<strong>the</strong> bank. As part of a credit programme operatedby <strong>the</strong> medium-sized enterprise, Promac,he was recently able to purchase a large metalw<strong>ork</strong>ing machine (valued at approximatelyUS$5000). Vincent and his wife, who is also amicro-entrepreneur, now make enough moneyto support <strong>the</strong>ir family, <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir kids to attendschool, and to pay off <strong>the</strong> loan on <strong>the</strong> machine.Be<strong>for</strong>e negotiating <strong>the</strong> loan <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> machine,Vincent commuted an hour and a half each wayto w<strong>ork</strong>. Now, he only travels once a week to<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal market to sell <strong>the</strong> metal pieces hemakes, and market demand is now outpacinghis production capacity. Vincent does not have atax number, and he pays no taxes to <strong>the</strong> federalor local government.Approximately 15 percent of Promac’s clientshave a private loan arrangement, similar to <strong>the</strong>one Vincent has. Segundo, Promac’s founder,says that a typical growth path <strong>for</strong> a businesslike Vincent’s would be to outgrow his homebasedoperation within two to three years, andto move into <strong>the</strong> industrial zone of <strong>the</strong> city. Bythis time, Vincent should be able to engage witha few larger clients who would no doubt insiston <strong>for</strong>mal tax receipts, eventually warranting <strong>the</strong>expense of registering <strong>the</strong> business. Once hemoves into <strong>the</strong> industrial area, Vincent says hewill register <strong>the</strong> business with <strong>the</strong> appropriatelocal municipal agencies to avoid some of <strong>the</strong>current hassles and to access larger loans from<strong>the</strong> banks. Hassles include intermittent electricityloss within San Martin de Porras, which has<strong>the</strong> potential to affect Vincent’s ability to re-payhis loan on time. In urban areas, 95 percent ofhouseholds have electricity, however this dropsto just 86 percent in <strong>the</strong> lowest economic quintile(Sociometro, 2007).Promac has a loan repayment rate of 100percent. Some clients are late with <strong>the</strong>ir paymentson occasion, but <strong>the</strong> company also offersa w<strong>ork</strong>-repayment option, where clients w<strong>ork</strong> in<strong>the</strong> Promac factory on an hourly basis as a wayof paying off <strong>the</strong> loan. Promac credits its successto a hands-on approach and a keen senseof <strong>the</strong> potential in its clientele.235


micro-finance activities. Micro-finance plays apivotal role in providing sustainable livelihoods bystimulating small businesses. Although microfinance77 is becoming increasingly available tomicro-entrepreneurs, frequently <strong>the</strong>ir only options<strong>for</strong> access to capital are through in<strong>for</strong>mal financialarrangements with priced transactions, rotatingsavings and credit associations (ROSCAs),or moneylenders who usually provide emergencyloans, often on usurious terms. The latter may notbe able to lend as per <strong>the</strong> needs of <strong>the</strong> growingenterprises. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, despite <strong>the</strong> positiveresponse to <strong>the</strong> progress of micro-finance, <strong>the</strong>rehas so far been little involvement by <strong>the</strong> world’slargest financial institutions in micro-financesuccesses. To be sure, <strong>the</strong>re are currently examplesof large private sector banks entering intorisk-sharing partnerships with NGO micro-financeinstitutions that merge <strong>the</strong> social mobilisationskills and rural presence of NGOs with <strong>the</strong> capitalresources and financial credibility of <strong>the</strong> bank.These ef<strong>for</strong>ts, however, need to be leveraged toenhance access to financial resources by microand small enterprises. The commonality betweenin<strong>for</strong>mal finance and micro-finance is in that <strong>the</strong>yconsider <strong>the</strong> households and <strong>the</strong> enterprise as aunit and are usually not concerned with how <strong>the</strong>loan is used — whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong> consumption, productiveinvestment or saving.Related to <strong>the</strong> issue of exploring <strong>the</strong> integrationof micro-finance with <strong>the</strong> financial sector and<strong>the</strong> roles of <strong>the</strong> private and public sectors, it isimportant to analyse <strong>the</strong> impact of policies 78 thatwill encourage greater financial sector involvementwith <strong>the</strong> markets and with demand by <strong>the</strong> poorand <strong>the</strong> disadvantaged. The micro-finance institutionshave induced more competition in <strong>the</strong> creditmarket and <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e lowered <strong>the</strong> credit interestrate that poor people have to pay. Currently <strong>the</strong>seinstitutions are unable to meet requests <strong>for</strong> sumsneeded to take micro-enterprises to a larger scale.SavingsIt is now widely recognised that <strong>the</strong> poor havea high propensity to save and that <strong>the</strong>re is aconsiderable demand <strong>for</strong> savings instruments andinstitutions. The creation over time of smoo<strong>the</strong>rflows of income can w<strong>ork</strong> to <strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> basis of anon-contractual insurance against natural, socialand physical shocks and stresses. In West Africa,in most savings-based micro-finance institutions(credit unions, village banks or savings, andcredit cooperatives), nearly six times as manypeople make deposits as take out loans at anypoint in time. 79Micro-insuranceEven though <strong>the</strong>re are important links betweenmicro-finance and micro-insurance, a related‘mantra’ that <strong>the</strong> poor are uninsurable still persists.Increasingly micro-insurance is a part of <strong>the</strong>developing micro-finance systems.Most entrepreneurs in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy,particularly micro and small entrepreneurs, donot have access to risk management and safetynetmechanism tools that large private firmsdo. These tools include a range of savings andinsurance products as well as more sophisticatedproducts that minimise risks from macroeconomicvariability, such as inflation, as well as shockand stresses from natural hazards and disasters.However, in<strong>for</strong>mal mechanisms such as savingsand o<strong>the</strong>r traditional risk management structures,80 have proven very expensive and <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>eunsustainable as long-term coping strategies. 81Access to insurance by <strong>the</strong> poor reduces <strong>the</strong>vulnerability of households and increases <strong>the</strong>irability to take advantage of opportunities. Eventhough micro-insurance is a nascent market, it236


provides protection to low-income people againstspecific risks and hazards in exchange <strong>for</strong> premiumpayments proportionate to <strong>the</strong> likelihoodand costs of <strong>the</strong> risks involved. 82 By reducing <strong>the</strong>impact of household losses that could exacerbate<strong>the</strong> poverty situation of households, micro-insurancecan enhance <strong>the</strong>ir stability and profitability.However, <strong>the</strong>se insurance instruments are notwidely available <strong>for</strong> managing risks <strong>for</strong> populationswith low incomes. If this kind of insurancecould be delivered cost-effectively through microfinanceinstitutions (MFIs), it could represent aprofitable segment <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> insurance industry.While previous attempts to launch such productshave not been entirely successful <strong>the</strong>y have pointed<strong>the</strong> way to eventual growth. There definitely isa need to be filled that would allow <strong>the</strong> poor toalleviate <strong>the</strong> economic impact of natural disasters.Also, micro-health insurance schemes offerreasonable guarantees of loan repayment since<strong>the</strong> insurance would provide <strong>for</strong> adequate medicaltreatment to <strong>the</strong> borrower in <strong>the</strong> event of serioushealth problems. Additionally, micro-insurancehas <strong>the</strong> potential to be used as collateral <strong>for</strong> borrowingadditional credit <strong>for</strong> business enterprises.Herein lies an important tool <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> promotionof equitable growth: enhanced access by <strong>the</strong>poor to inclusive and gender-responsive financialproducts and services (like micro-insurance),supported by policies, social institutions and newtechnologies that reduce market barriers andtransaction costs. These interventions toge<strong>the</strong>rwith capacity development at human, institutionaland system-wide levels, show <strong>the</strong> promiseof reducing vulnerabilities among <strong>the</strong> poor byassisting <strong>the</strong>m in creating assets, promotingentrepreneurship, improving service delivery, andstreng<strong>the</strong>ning livelihoods.The private and <strong>for</strong>mal sectors are capable ofproviding micro-insurance products, as <strong>the</strong>y candesign and offer sustainable and long-term riskreduction strategies that are also profitable. Thisrole is being explored comprehensively, both as abusiness model and as an intervention <strong>for</strong> socialprotection. In <strong>the</strong> process, it will be important tolearn just how micro-insurance relates to governmentpolicies, role of government, and <strong>the</strong>public sector. For now, it is encouraging that asignificant number of insurers are keen to explore<strong>the</strong> low-income market; in time, <strong>the</strong> viability ofa micro-insurance product will be determined by<strong>the</strong> demand and its attractiveness, as well as by<strong>the</strong> number of potential clients. Currently, <strong>the</strong>ability to pay and incentives to fill <strong>the</strong> demand <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> insurance products are common barriers <strong>for</strong>consumers and suppliers. There is anticipationthat <strong>the</strong>se barriers can be overcome, in part, byproviding an operational linkage between microinsuranceand remittances.RemittancesWhile <strong>the</strong> search <strong>for</strong> a better life and livelihoodsdrive rural-urban migration, <strong>the</strong> root causes ofinternational migration derive from <strong>the</strong> majoreconomic, demographic, and social disparities aswell as conflicts, climate change and environmentaldegradation or disasters. Remittances constitute<strong>the</strong> most tangible contribution of migrants topoverty alleviation. A better understanding of howremittances are used would in<strong>for</strong>m public policyand development interventions <strong>for</strong> migration andfinancial services and <strong>for</strong> enterprise development,livelihoods streng<strong>the</strong>ning and provisions of o<strong>the</strong>rbasic services. It is equally important is to ensurethat <strong>the</strong> money reaches rural areas as well aso<strong>the</strong>r areas where large populations are still outside<strong>the</strong> banking system with no access to diversefinancial goods and services that can improve<strong>the</strong>ir quality of life.237


Remittances — <strong>the</strong> transfer of funds fromone place to ano<strong>the</strong>r, from urban to ruralareas or by developing country nationals sendingearnings back home — can play an instrumentalrole in providing greater access to resources andto safety- net mechanisms <strong>for</strong> entrepreneurs at<strong>the</strong> bottom of <strong>the</strong> pyramid. Remittances constitute<strong>the</strong> second largest capital flow to developingcountries. It is less than capital that is investeddirectly by private companies but more thanofficial aid. In 2006 remittances in <strong>the</strong> developingworld amounted to about US$206 billion. Inmany developing countries, amounts sent homeby migrants supporting family and friends weremany times <strong>the</strong> value of official government-togovernmentaid flows.If <strong>the</strong> transaction costs of remittances can bereduced, <strong>for</strong>mal channels will substitute in<strong>for</strong>maltransfers. 83 Fundamental issues involved in makingthis change range from accessible technology,hours of availability, and efficiency of transactionand regulations, to <strong>the</strong> profit margins by <strong>the</strong> institutionsengaged in <strong>the</strong> process. 84 While it is expectedthat <strong>the</strong> technology would play an importantrole in lowering <strong>the</strong> cost of remittances, newbusiness models and a regulatory environmenthold <strong>the</strong> key to greater access to <strong>the</strong> services, andefficiency of <strong>the</strong> transfer process. Better servicecan provide greater profits by integrating remittancesmore fully into financial services offerings<strong>for</strong> migrants and <strong>the</strong>ir families. Although <strong>the</strong>issues are complex, remittance are important <strong>for</strong>developing countries as <strong>the</strong> amount can provideaccess to additional financial resources andultimately to <strong>the</strong> creation and sustainability oflivelihoods.Case Study:Construmex (Mexico) — HelpingMigrants with RemittancesOverview: Construmex helps thousands ofMexican migrants in <strong>the</strong> U.S. purchase andbuild homes <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>mselves and <strong>the</strong>ir familiesback in Mexico.Constraint: Construmex recognised that itsearlier model of serving low-income clientsin Mexico would not w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> migrants in<strong>the</strong> U.S., as <strong>the</strong> latter approached commercialtransactions with extreme caution. Thecompany lacked adequate market researchto determine how best to proceed.Solution: Construmex partnered with Mexicanconsulates in <strong>the</strong> U.S. to conduct marketresearch on <strong>the</strong> needs of <strong>the</strong> migrant population.Following <strong>the</strong>se surveys, it developed anew ‘cash-to-asset’ transfer service that wasoffered through migrant associations.Source: UNDP, ‘Growing Inclusive Markets — Business W<strong>ork</strong>s <strong>for</strong>Development- Development W<strong>ork</strong>s <strong>for</strong> Business.’ June 2007There are several ongoing initiatives at this timeundertaken by different countries, developmentagencies and institutions, and <strong>the</strong> learning isevolving. The governments of origin and destinationhave to w<strong>ork</strong> toge<strong>the</strong>r with multilateralorganisations, private sector, and diaspora ando<strong>the</strong>r stakeholders to create options, tools andincentives to maximise <strong>the</strong> development benefitsof remittances. These incentives and tools can belinked to <strong>the</strong> transfers <strong>the</strong>mselves (e.g. throughsavings, credit, micro-insurance and micro-pensionschemes) or focus on mobilising savings generatedby remittances towards productive investments(made by <strong>the</strong> migrant, <strong>the</strong> recipients or a localentrepreneur). This would buttress streamlinedand gender-responsive remittance policies andregulations, and streng<strong>the</strong>n capacity developmentat human, institutional and system-wide levels.These collaborative ef<strong>for</strong>ts can also catalyse public238


private-partnerships (PPPs) that can lead to innovativedemand-based products and services <strong>for</strong>meeting <strong>the</strong> needs of <strong>the</strong> poor people.To summarize: an enabling environment, capacityand institutions that will enhance access tofinance and safety net mechanisms are critical<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurs at <strong>the</strong> bottom of <strong>the</strong>pyramid and require innovative approaches.Remittances can be an attractive business <strong>for</strong>micro-finance institutions and a valuable additionalfinancial service <strong>for</strong> current and potentialmicro-finance clients. Also, micro-insurance canassist in increasing <strong>the</strong> demand <strong>for</strong> micro-financeand potentially take micro-finance activities to alarger scale.Public-Private PartnershipsThe in<strong>for</strong>mal economy is particularly dynamic anddemands a high level of responsiveness from <strong>the</strong>state. Even though globalisation is significantlychanging <strong>the</strong> traditional role of <strong>the</strong> State, <strong>the</strong> roleof <strong>the</strong> government must remain central in <strong>the</strong> developmentchoices. One compelling reason is that‘in most re<strong>for</strong>ming countries <strong>the</strong> private sectordid not step in to fill <strong>the</strong> vacuum when <strong>the</strong> publicsector withdrew.’ 85At <strong>the</strong> same time, developing countries arerecognising <strong>the</strong> importance of markets and <strong>the</strong>yunderstand that markets have to be created andgoverned. And sometimes <strong>the</strong> private sector hasto be motivated to do what needs to be donethrough <strong>the</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>ning of <strong>the</strong> policy environment,and through incentives and removal ofbarriers <strong>for</strong> market creation. An efficient privatesector depends on a sound domestic macroenvironment that fosters good trade policies andinstitutional foundations, and adequate capacityto maximise benefits from <strong>the</strong> macro globalenvironment and to promote distributional equity.The private sector is keen to harmonise privateinterest with public interest because, inter alia,it has started recognising <strong>the</strong> potential businessopportunities. Accordingly, <strong>the</strong> private sector isactively promoting new approaches to alleviatingpoverty, opening opportunities <strong>for</strong> all concerned,including <strong>the</strong> poor people and <strong>the</strong> private sectorcompanies. While private financial institutionsare willing to develop innovative partnershipmodels to provide access to inclusive financialservices, <strong>the</strong>y need assistance in <strong>for</strong>mulatingappropriate policies and streng<strong>the</strong>ning capacitiesthat would remove barriers to market creationand expansion of market access to entrepreneursat <strong>the</strong> base of <strong>the</strong> pyramid. Governments, meanwhile,should be encouraging private financial institutionsto garner savings, long-term credit andmarket-based social protection instruments in ruraland underserved areas, 86 hence <strong>the</strong> emphasison public-private partnerships. Also, partnershipwith <strong>the</strong> private sector is no longer simply aboutmobilisation of resources; it is also about actingon knowledge gained from <strong>the</strong> wealth of collectiveexperience about entrepreneurship, managementskills and global netw<strong>ork</strong>ing.The challenge to make <strong>the</strong> ‘missing markets’play an economic role in job creation andservice delivery lies less in finding technologicalsolutions to production and distribution and morein structuring institutions, capacities, incentivesand regulations. And, if sustainable, high qualityand af<strong>for</strong>dable basic services are actually to bedelivered to <strong>the</strong> poor and disadvantaged, capacitiesmust be built to engage <strong>the</strong> talents and energiesof <strong>the</strong> greater community and to allow <strong>for</strong>real and meaningful ownership of <strong>the</strong> activities of<strong>the</strong> different stakeholders.Public-private partnerships hold great promise inthis endeavour, especially if <strong>the</strong>y were given anenabling environment that removed barriers to<strong>the</strong> entry by <strong>the</strong> smaller and community-based239


Case Study:Durban: A Heterogeneous Solution Through Public Private PartnershipThe city of Durban in South Africa, took anon-restrictive approach to street vending. Itdemarcated sites throughout <strong>the</strong> city; changed<strong>the</strong> legal framew<strong>ork</strong> that governed street tradingfrom criminal to administrative law; decreased<strong>the</strong> cost of trading spaces; and guaranteed servicessuch as basic shelter, solid waste removal,water, toilets, lighting, and storage facilities.The city also created an appeal committee offive members, of whom at least one was requiredto be a street vendor, where municipaldecisions can be reviewed.However, as <strong>the</strong> majority of in<strong>for</strong>mal businesseswere in <strong>the</strong> traditional medicine sector, it wasnecessary to provide access to market. Over30,000 people, mostly women, w<strong>ork</strong>ed in thissector. Through direct intervention, Durbanbuilt a dedicated market <strong>for</strong> traditional medicinetraders with shelter, storage, water, andtoilet facilities. It also trained ga<strong>the</strong>rers on cultivatingproducts and sustainable harvest techniquesand is currently planning to establisha company to procure materials from growers,process <strong>the</strong>m in partnership with a pharmaceuticalfirm, and market <strong>the</strong> products.(Source: Lund and Skinner, 2005.)Case Study:Buy-back Centres <strong>for</strong> Waste Collectors:A Public-Private-Community Partnership ModelWaste collectors are amongst <strong>the</strong> poorest ofthose w<strong>ork</strong>ing in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. In SouthAfrica, since legislated racial segregation ofurban areas was abolished, <strong>the</strong>re have beenincreasing numbers of waste collectors operatingthroughout its cities. They are largely blackwomen whose incomes are extremely low. In <strong>the</strong>mid-1990s <strong>the</strong> Self Employed Women’s Union(SEWU) organised cardboard collectors in <strong>the</strong>inner city of Durban/Thekwini. The union foundthat <strong>the</strong>se collectors were innumerate and oftenexploited by unscrupulous middle-men, and itlobbied local government to assist <strong>the</strong>m.Through SEWU’s activism, and <strong>the</strong> understandingby <strong>the</strong> City Council that waste collectionprovided a livelihood <strong>for</strong> many residents, a buybackcentre was established in <strong>the</strong> inner city.This is a public-private-community partnership.The Council provided a small plot of centrallylocatedland that was converted into <strong>the</strong> centre,and a large private-sector recycler provided <strong>the</strong>scales, storage containers <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> cardboard andtrolleys <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> collectors. SEWU w<strong>ork</strong>ed alongsidecity officials to design <strong>the</strong> interventionand trained <strong>the</strong> cardboard collectors on how toweight <strong>the</strong>ir cardboard. Through this intervention,<strong>the</strong> collectors sold <strong>the</strong>ir cardboard directlyto <strong>the</strong> recycling company. This has substantiallyincreased <strong>the</strong> (albeit still low) incomes of <strong>the</strong>sewaste collectors. The success of <strong>the</strong> inner citybuy-back centre has led to <strong>the</strong> Council establishinga number of similar centres throughout<strong>the</strong> city. (Source: Mgingqizana, 2002.)240


enterprises. Developing effective skills <strong>for</strong> nurturingpartnerships, en<strong>for</strong>cing transparent rule of law(including efficient contracting and procurementprocesses), and improving managerial capabilitycould go a long way to encourage <strong>the</strong> creationand <strong>the</strong>n to sustain such PPPs. Their energiescould be tapped to meet <strong>the</strong> needs of <strong>the</strong> poor <strong>for</strong>basic services. For instance, it is estimated that<strong>the</strong> achievement of <strong>the</strong> MDG goals <strong>for</strong> water andsanitation will require enormous annual budgetaryoutlays. A very different and more manageablescenario is <strong>for</strong>eseen if ef<strong>for</strong>ts to achieve<strong>the</strong>se targets were supplemented by servicedelivery through PPPs, particularly if <strong>the</strong> localcommunities were empowered to manage <strong>the</strong>irneeds through effective value-chain strategies. Ifeffectively <strong>for</strong>mulated, PPPs would generate benefitsbeyond <strong>the</strong> obvious ones of providing jobsand livelihoods. Health in <strong>the</strong> communities couldbe improved and children could have greater opportunitiesto attend schools.Economic success requires getting <strong>the</strong> balanceright between <strong>the</strong> government and <strong>the</strong> market interms of who should provide <strong>the</strong> goods and servicesand how <strong>the</strong>y should be provided. The balanceis, of course, country-specific and dependson <strong>the</strong> level of development. While recognising<strong>the</strong> critical role of governments in creating foundations<strong>for</strong> a healthy and dynamic private sector,it is vital to develop innovative models of PPPsboth at <strong>the</strong> local levels as well as national levels,to harness resources, capacity and skills of <strong>the</strong>private sector to benefit national development. 87influences all development activities. At <strong>the</strong> sametime, assurance is needed that <strong>the</strong> supportingstate and public policies are functioning, that <strong>the</strong>necessary regulation <strong>for</strong> creating greater equity isin place, and above all — that <strong>the</strong> arrangementw<strong>ork</strong>s.To Sum UpThe discussion in this section has focussed onsound economic governance that provides policies,laws, regulations, institutions, practices,and individuals to support a strategic partnershipof government, private sector and civil society <strong>for</strong>delivery of basic goods and services and accessto markets. In addition, issues were explored concerningaccess to finance and safety net mechanismswhich are critical <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal entrepreneurs,particularly micro-finance, micro-insuranceand <strong>the</strong> matter of remittances and savings amongvarious o<strong>the</strong>r financial services and portfolios.The next section focuses on solutions that authoritiesand businesses (i.e., bottom-up and viceversa) have developed based on real life problemsand experiences. Experiences and solutions comefrom all aspects of business life and several differentcountries. An advantage of evidence-basedsolutions is that measures successfully adoptedby one country may be replicated in o<strong>the</strong>rs, withnecessary modifications.Successful mobilisation of <strong>the</strong> communities,whe<strong>the</strong>r through <strong>the</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>ts of <strong>the</strong> government,<strong>the</strong> private sector or NGOs, represents collectiveaction at <strong>the</strong> local level. Though <strong>the</strong> interventionsinvolved in w<strong>ork</strong>ing <strong>for</strong> new economicgrowth outcomes reflect local interventions, <strong>the</strong>irimplementation recognises a global context that241


5. Institutional changesand legal toolsmaking a difference <strong>for</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises —an evidence-based approachIn <strong>the</strong> earlier sections of this chapter, we referredto constraints and barriers businesses have facedin <strong>the</strong>ir operations, as well as <strong>the</strong> need to broadenaccess to markets, services and infrastructure.We now focus on solutions that authorities andbusinesses have developed based on real-lifesituations, problems, and experiences. Experiencescome from a number of countries and fromall aspects of business life.The main advantage of evidence-based solutionsis that measures successfully adopted byone country can — with necessary modifications— be replicated in o<strong>the</strong>rs. Instead of academicdiscussions, realities exist on <strong>the</strong> ground and canbe borrowed and implemented.The <strong>for</strong>mat we adopt <strong>for</strong> evidence-based solutionsare <strong>the</strong> same — from business start-up tobusiness exit — as described in our discussion ofbarriers and constraints to keep con<strong>for</strong>mity andmaintain <strong>the</strong> linkage. We also present cases ofre<strong>for</strong>ms that have taken place both from <strong>the</strong>perspectives of <strong>the</strong> top (due to sustained pressuresfrom <strong>the</strong> bottom) as well as initiativesundertaken at <strong>the</strong> local/grass-root level or by <strong>the</strong>private sector.Improvement in <strong>the</strong> quality of institutions in aneconomy has to proceed simultaneously with trans<strong>for</strong>mationof <strong>the</strong> nature and efficiency of its in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy. Learning from <strong>the</strong> institution-buildingexperience of <strong>the</strong> industrialised countries, andthose in transition, as well as from o<strong>the</strong>r developingcountries, can be valuable. There are severalgood practice examples from around <strong>the</strong> world toillustrate how constraints of in<strong>for</strong>mal businesseshave been successfully addressed through institutionaland policy changes. At <strong>the</strong> same time, nationaland local-level institutional changes can beinitiated implicitly by introducing new economicactivities to provide direct and measurable benefitsto those who will be influenced by <strong>the</strong> institutionalchange. Ability of <strong>the</strong> population impacted by<strong>the</strong> institutional change to recognise <strong>the</strong> tangiblebenefits provides ownership. And, <strong>the</strong> economicactivity becomes an agent <strong>for</strong>, and a catalyst of,derived demand <strong>for</strong> appropriate institutions. 89 Forinstance, economic empowerment based on economicactivity is a step towards gender equality, 90even though <strong>the</strong>se are not synonymous with it.Linking creative economic activities with businessrights in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy has an addedadvantage in that it allows <strong>for</strong> a learning-by-doingapproach to implementing institutional re<strong>for</strong>ms.It also allows a synergistic linkage betweenre<strong>for</strong>ms from above, including those initiated bygovernments or promoted by international organisationswith effective action from below — <strong>for</strong>example, by civil society organisations and <strong>the</strong>organisations of <strong>the</strong> poor <strong>the</strong>mselves.Legal empowerment entails making laws andregulations appropriate and relevant to <strong>the</strong> realitiesof in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses. Some successfulinnovations are discussed below. It also requiresa just and fair system of en<strong>for</strong>cement of laws.Specifically, it implies:• A competent, independent judiciary, applying<strong>the</strong> law equally and evenly on all members of<strong>the</strong> community. Essential are education of <strong>the</strong>legal profession, full publication and disseminationof legal texts including judicial decisions;• Transparent, coherent laws, including laws <strong>for</strong>242


Case Study:‘Tell us how to make legal mechanisms and tools w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses.’ President Benjamin Mkapa, TanzaniaIn 2005 President Benjamin Mkapa of Tanzaniaproposed that <strong>the</strong> next government should speedup <strong>the</strong> process of bringing in<strong>for</strong>mal businesseswithin <strong>the</strong> legal ambit to shore up achievementsrecorded and spur fur<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> country’s economicgrowth. The president made <strong>the</strong> remarks whenhe launched a report on <strong>the</strong> Diagnosis Phase of<strong>the</strong> Property and Business Formalisation Programme<strong>for</strong> Tanzania. Quoting <strong>the</strong> 2005 GlobalCompetitive Report released by <strong>the</strong> World EconomicForum, Mkapa noted that Tanzania hadclimbed 11 places above last year’s rating andovertaken Uganda and Kenya partly because of<strong>the</strong> contribution by in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses. In orderto take Tanzania to <strong>the</strong> next level of development,<strong>the</strong> President specifically sought answersto <strong>the</strong> following:a) How are we going to turn all this recognitioninto something accessible and beneficial to<strong>the</strong> 98 per cent of business operating outside<strong>the</strong> legal system?b) How can we enable people to leverage <strong>the</strong>irparticipation in this competitive environmentwhen probably 89 percent of <strong>the</strong>ir assets areheld in <strong>the</strong> extra-legal sector?c) What legal re<strong>for</strong>ms should be instituted torecognise, protect and ’<strong>for</strong>malise’ of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maloperators’ assets?d) What needs to be done to ensure our peoplebenefit from <strong>the</strong> growing <strong>for</strong>mal and marketeconomy?e) Due to lack of recognition legally, in<strong>for</strong>malentrepreneurs have created <strong>the</strong>ir own mechanismsof documentation, registration, fungibilityand collateral, and testament.These in<strong>for</strong>mal entrepreneurs have developed archetypesof business organisations and expandedmarkets outside <strong>the</strong> legal sector,’ he added.‘How can we bring <strong>the</strong>se organisations into <strong>the</strong>mainstream and provide recognition? And <strong>the</strong>real challenge is to use <strong>the</strong>se archetypes as abasis <strong>for</strong> a new system wherein people can relateto and access, and thus bring down <strong>the</strong> barriersthat stifle entrepreneurship. How to remove thosebarriers that exclude <strong>the</strong>m from participating in<strong>the</strong> markets we seek to create, and that retardour poverty-reduction ef<strong>for</strong>ts. Mkapa said Tanzaniacontinues to be excluded from <strong>the</strong> benefits ofan expanded market economy, and it was time tobring <strong>the</strong>m in. He called <strong>for</strong> support from stakeholdersand development partners, non-governmentalorganisations, financial institutions ,ando<strong>the</strong>rs in <strong>the</strong> protection and <strong>for</strong>malisation of <strong>the</strong>hard-won assets and business of <strong>the</strong> majority ofpoor Tanzanians. Source: Guardian, 2005-10-06<strong>the</strong> protection and facilitation of business;• Freedom of <strong>the</strong> press, and adequately paidjournalists to shelter <strong>the</strong>m from bribery;• En<strong>for</strong>cement officers who apply <strong>the</strong> law uni<strong>for</strong>mlyto all;• Ease of entry into <strong>for</strong>mal business so that variousbusiness <strong>for</strong>ms are quickly and cheaply<strong>for</strong>med, some to limit <strong>the</strong> owners’ liability to<strong>the</strong>ir investment in <strong>the</strong> business;• Significant ef<strong>for</strong>t to reduce grand corruptionand, ultimately, to rein<strong>for</strong>ce social norms thatconstrain petty corruption.Of <strong>the</strong> emerging business laws in some Africancountries, 91 are an example of an important243


step toward this kind of structure. They do not,however, fully protect transactions from distortionswithin <strong>the</strong> national judicial systems, and<strong>the</strong>y have not yet generated <strong>the</strong> transparency<strong>the</strong>y are designed to provide as nei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> decisionsnor <strong>the</strong> filings have yet been systematicallycomputerized. The laws also do not address whocontrols <strong>the</strong> military. They do, however, create avocabulary and a virtual <strong>for</strong>um <strong>for</strong> discussion oflegal predictability and, generally, of <strong>the</strong> rule oflaw; in this way <strong>the</strong> laws have facilitated discussionsamong actors in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy,including business people as well as lawyers,academics and judges. The same vocabularyand <strong>for</strong>um allow social norms underlying <strong>for</strong>mallaws to influence <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, too, <strong>for</strong>example when business people with one foot ineach economy are vectors <strong>for</strong> transfer of in<strong>for</strong>mation.The appearance in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy ofrelationships and documents mimicking those in<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy suggests <strong>the</strong> power of suchtransfers from <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy.Innovations which DemonstrateBusiness Rights and LegalEmpowermentWhile business regulations vary from country tocountry, and from municipality to municipality,<strong>the</strong>y usually include most of <strong>the</strong> features bulletedbelow. Responses to <strong>the</strong> obligations thatfollow from such regulations are appropriate to<strong>the</strong> circumstances of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal entrepreneursand may be termed ‘empowering’. Most countrieswould expect <strong>the</strong> following from a <strong>for</strong>mally recognisedbusiness:• Incorporation of <strong>the</strong> business as a legalentity.• Inclusion in a business registry at <strong>the</strong> national,regional, or municipal level.• Registration with <strong>the</strong> national tax authority.• Registration of employees in pension/health/o<strong>the</strong>r national social security schemes.• Acquisition of building permits, at <strong>the</strong> municipallevel.• Acquisition of operating and o<strong>the</strong>r licenses,at <strong>the</strong> municipal level.• Approval of health officials upon inspection(especially <strong>for</strong> sales of food), at <strong>the</strong> nationaland/or municipal levels.• Safety approval from local fire officials.Starting a BusinessSome of <strong>the</strong> best practices 92 adopted across <strong>the</strong>world to simplify business start-up <strong>for</strong>malitiesand registration are as follows:1. Diagnose <strong>the</strong> problem:Australia: A task<strong>for</strong>ce was created to measure <strong>the</strong>administrative burden, resulting in <strong>the</strong> establishmentof a Business License In<strong>for</strong>mation Systems(BLIS) as a one-stop-shop service designed to deliverpertinent governmental in<strong>for</strong>mation to smallbusinesses regarding licenses, application <strong>for</strong>msand contact details. The results of BLIS are veryimpressive. They have reduced <strong>the</strong> administrativeburden <strong>for</strong> business by reducing <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mationsearch cost incurred in trying to establish <strong>the</strong>irregulatory compliance obligations. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore,15,000 people use this system every year; and in<strong>the</strong> nine months between September 1999 andMay 1999, BLIS generated more than 13,500fact sheets and reports <strong>for</strong> new and existing businessvia <strong>the</strong> Internet alone.Mexico: a special deregulation unit was set upunder <strong>the</strong> Ministry of Industry and Commerce toreview all existing business <strong>for</strong>malities, includingstart-up requirements. The comprehensiveness of<strong>the</strong> approach led to a more fundamental re<strong>for</strong>mthan if <strong>the</strong> government had sought fast results.2. Provide adequate training and resources to244


Case Study:Business Registration Re<strong>for</strong>m in UgandaIn Uganda, firms must apply <strong>for</strong> annual ‘tradelicenses’, which combine basic registration of<strong>the</strong>ir status with o<strong>the</strong>r approvals. This processis a major deterrent to <strong>for</strong>malising businesses.It takes an average of two days to obtain <strong>the</strong>license at an average compliance cost of about20 percent of per capita GDP. Administrationincludes cashiers <strong>for</strong> fee payments, registrars<strong>for</strong> reviewing paperw<strong>ork</strong> and issuing <strong>the</strong> license,a site visit by a health and safety inspector, andapproval by <strong>the</strong> Local Chairman.Little of this is really necessary, except <strong>for</strong> afew firms which pose significant risks to publichealth or security. The DFID project introduceda simplified trade licensing process in Entebbemunicipality, involving only provision of basicin<strong>for</strong>mation by <strong>the</strong> entrepreneur, payment of afee, and immediate issue of <strong>the</strong> license document— all in one stop. This re<strong>for</strong>m was foundto have brought <strong>the</strong> following benefits:A cheaper & shorter process: compliance costdropped by 75 percent and is now estimated at2 percent of per capita GDP. Average registrationtime is now 30 minutes, down from twodays.Better business-government relations: businessesfeel that <strong>the</strong> attitude of <strong>the</strong> registration staffis much more positive and pro-business.More businesses registered: registration levelshave improved by 43 percent. In <strong>the</strong> first year,four times more businesses registered than in<strong>the</strong> previous year.More government revenue: total revenue collectionhas increased by 40 percent through moreregistrations. Individual businesses pay less onaverage.Reduced administrative costs <strong>for</strong> government:Entebbe municipality estimates a 10 percentreduction in administrative costs. Administrativetime ef<strong>for</strong>t by staff is down by 25 percent.There are reduced waiting lines and hassles <strong>for</strong>businesses.Health & safety inspections more targeted &prioritized: inspectors can now target <strong>the</strong>ir visitson high risk businesses.Better knowledge of business profiles/sectors: anew computerized system and improved compliancegives <strong>the</strong> local authority better in<strong>for</strong>mation.These re<strong>for</strong>ms were implemented withoutchanges to national level legislation whichwould have been very difficult and slow toachieve. Instead, o<strong>the</strong>r legal means were foundto make change. In cases such as this, regulatorybarriers to <strong>for</strong>malisation can be reducedwithout large-scale legal change, but ra<strong>the</strong>rthrough small incremental change. The Entebbeexperience is now being replicated in o<strong>the</strong>r localauthorities in Uganda.licensing authorities:Australia: Training to licensing authorities on <strong>the</strong>use of new technologies <strong>for</strong> business registration,having <strong>the</strong> greatest positive effect on small businessesand micro enterprises, which generally donot have resources to spend on legal assistance.Ceará, Brazil: Technical assistance given to applicants,many of whom are illiterate or semi-illiterate.Government prepares material <strong>for</strong> SMEs,which explain <strong>the</strong>ir rights and responsibilities on245


key topics in simple and clear language.Eritrea: Legal assistance provided to SMEs tomake better use of <strong>the</strong>ir rights and instruments.3. Business Help Centres (BHC) - Create singleaccess point <strong>for</strong> business <strong>for</strong> entrepreneurs:Turkey: a one-stop registration launched in June2003 by combining seven procedures into a singlevisit to <strong>the</strong> company registry. The time to start abusiness was cut from 38 days to nine. In addition,application <strong>for</strong>ms were unified and shortened, andregistry officers were trained in customer relations.The cost fell by a third and <strong>the</strong> number of registrationsshot up by 18 percent, almost halving <strong>the</strong>time to start a business — from 23 days to 13.Portugal: at <strong>the</strong> Centro de Formalidades deEmpresa all company registration procedures areper<strong>for</strong>med in only three visits.4. Introduction of standardised <strong>for</strong>ms resulted insignificant reduction in rejection rates:In <strong>the</strong> United Kingdom rejection rates went downby eight percent, in Malaysia by 11 percent andin Costa Rica by 14 percent. These can cover allbusiness <strong>for</strong>ms: sole proprietorship, partnership,limited liability, or corporation.5. Electronic registration, online <strong>for</strong>ms and registrydata base in Denmark, Italy, UK, and Norway:electronic registration, an innovative and efficientprocedure, has become norm.Australia and Canada: The Internet can be usedto file business registrations, which cuts <strong>the</strong> administrativecost by more than 50 percent.Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands: <strong>the</strong> Ministry of Economic Affairshas launched a programme of ‘Forms on Line.’Forms are unified under this programme. Registrydatabase should be updated continually andaccessible by <strong>the</strong> Internet. A system should bein place <strong>for</strong> real time access to <strong>the</strong> database byinspectorates and o<strong>the</strong>rs who need <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mation,such as tax, customs, pension, and socialsecurity authorities.6. Cut <strong>the</strong> newspaper publication requirement:Serbia and Montenegro abolished <strong>the</strong> requirementto publish a notice in <strong>the</strong> official gazette.Instead, companies announce <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>for</strong>mation on<strong>the</strong> registry’s website.7. Allow businesses to start activities immediatelyafter registration:Germany and Italy allow companies to beginactivities as soon as <strong>the</strong>y file <strong>the</strong> required in<strong>for</strong>mation(as long as it does not involve dangerousactivities). This eliminates ex ante barriers tostart-ups.México: <strong>the</strong> government created <strong>the</strong> Sistema deApertura Rápida de Empresas (SARE), which reduced<strong>the</strong> number of federal <strong>for</strong>malities to open alow-risk business <strong>for</strong> individuals (tax registration)and <strong>for</strong> business (tax registration and enterpriseregistration). Under <strong>the</strong> SARE system, it takesone w<strong>ork</strong>ing day to comply with federal startup<strong>for</strong>malities <strong>for</strong> low-risk activities (specifiedin annex to <strong>the</strong> decree). As of November 2002,more than 226 000 individuals and 1,400 legalentities have received <strong>the</strong>ir tax and enterpriseregistration under this scheme.8. Impose a ‘silence is consent’ rule:This means that once <strong>the</strong> deadline had passed,<strong>the</strong> business is automatically considered registered.This approach, pioneered in Italy, iscurrently en<strong>for</strong>ced in Armenia, Georgia, andMorocco. All four are among <strong>the</strong> world’s fastest20 percent <strong>for</strong> registering a business.9. Reduce or scrap <strong>the</strong> minimum capital requirement<strong>for</strong> private limited liability companies:In Bosnia and Herzegovina <strong>the</strong> capital requirementhas been reduced by half.In France, <strong>the</strong> requirement was abolished.246


10. Establish a single business identificationnumber to expedite and track <strong>the</strong> processing ofofficial requests:Oregon: <strong>the</strong> single business identificationnumber is used when reporting, paying, makingenquiries about employment-related obligations— such as withholding, unemployment, andtransit taxes — and w<strong>ork</strong>er’s compensation assessments.Ireland: brought toge<strong>the</strong>r tax registration details<strong>for</strong> income, social security, and value-added taxesunder a single registration number. This practicehas also been introduced also in o<strong>the</strong>r Europeancountries.11. Involve <strong>the</strong> private sector in registration:Serbia: <strong>the</strong> independent agency registers businessthrough a netw<strong>ork</strong> of service centres strategicallylocated around <strong>the</strong> country, and throughon-line and mail registration.Italy recently eliminated <strong>the</strong> role of <strong>the</strong> courtsaltoge<strong>the</strong>r and enjoys substantial efficiencies asa result. The trend in Europe is toward administrativemanagement of registries and away fromlegal process involving courts and notaries.(A recent study 93 <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> European Commissionfound that key drivers of good registration areimprovements in internal efficiency in public bodiesthrough better management techniques andper<strong>for</strong>mance measures, accountability, and userconsultation, which implies a client-orientationfocused on business needs. The study found thatreduction in <strong>the</strong> involvement of court notaries ando<strong>the</strong>r legal bodies were associated with substantialefficiency improvements.)12. Licensing Re<strong>for</strong>ms — rationalisation:Russia: <strong>the</strong> new law on licenses significantly reduced<strong>the</strong> number of activities subject to licensing,reduced <strong>the</strong> license fee, and extended <strong>the</strong>term of validity of a license to at least five years(from three years). After <strong>the</strong> adoption of <strong>the</strong> newlaw, <strong>the</strong> percentage of <strong>the</strong> enterprises that applied<strong>for</strong> licenses and permits dropped by a third.13. ‘Get out of <strong>the</strong> Courts.’ Eliminate <strong>the</strong> need<strong>for</strong> mandatory use of both notaries and judgesfrom registration:Bosnia-Herzegovina will make registration anadministrative process, without resorting to <strong>the</strong>courts. Also eliminates <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> judges.Italy: registration was taken out of <strong>the</strong> courts,saving three months.Serbia and Montenegro adopted legislation to do<strong>the</strong> same in May 2004. The benefits are large.Entrepreneurs in countries where registrationrequires a judicial process spend 14 more days tostart a business.Operating a Business1. Reduce <strong>the</strong> number of inspections by governmentauthorities with <strong>the</strong> exception of those areaswhere regular inspections are needed due to <strong>the</strong>nature of transactions. Inspections, in general,are based on ad hoc system in terms of documentrequirements, interpretation of documents,and intention of inspectors. They usually lead tobribes and corruption:Russia: According to a new Inspection <strong>Law</strong>, anyone state agency can carry out no more than oneinspection of one and <strong>the</strong> same firm in two years.The number of inspections dropped by a third.2. Private inspections and certification —alternatives to administrative regulation:Australia: a model involving private and third-partycertification of building compliance by competentbuilding professionals has been incorporatedat <strong>the</strong> national level. It involves <strong>the</strong> developmentof a model of rational building legislation devel-247


oped as part of a long-term regulatory harmonisationprocess in this area.Dubai has implemented this system, while Japanand Malaysia have expressed considerable interest.Finland introduced several types of privateinspection in 2004, such as <strong>for</strong> foundation, steelw<strong>ork</strong>sand electrical w<strong>ork</strong>. All Nordic countries aswell as Australia, Canada, Ghana, Kenya, SouthAfrica, Uganda, <strong>the</strong> United Kingdom and Zambiahave adopted risk-based inspections.3. Simplified and transparent taxation system:Uzbekistan: which used to have a complex andfrequently changeable tax system, recently introduceda fixed simplified taxation system <strong>for</strong> SMEs— a great benefit to individual entrepreneurs,micro-firms, and small enterprises. Instead ofvarious national and local taxes, <strong>the</strong>y pay ei<strong>the</strong>r afixed or a unified tax.Russia: <strong>the</strong> new Taxation System <strong>Law</strong> gave firmsincentives to use a simplified tax system. Insteadof VAT, profit, sales, and property taxes, smallenterprises can pay one unified tax. (Accordingto <strong>the</strong> old 1995 Russia law, SMEs had to pay 10percent of profit <strong>for</strong> federal and 20 percent <strong>for</strong> regionalbudgets; 3.3 percent of revenue <strong>for</strong> federaland 6.7 percent <strong>for</strong> regional budgets, if revenuewas below 7.5 million roubles and employmentbelow 20 people. The new Russia law requires15 percent of profit or six percent of revenue, ifrevenue is below 11 million roubles and employmentbelow 100 people.)4. Tax Identification Numbers:Australia: introduced ID numbers in real estatetransactions and banking and financial activities.The aim is to reduce tax evasion and unreportedactivities by employing computerised tax officesand management in<strong>for</strong>mation systems, setting upregional in<strong>for</strong>mation and audit centres and establishinga system to track unpaid taxes.5. Electronic Tax declarations:Mexico is using instruments such as electronicfunds transfer submission of declarations through<strong>the</strong> Internet instead of paperw<strong>ork</strong>. The resultsof this practice have been astonishing: reducedpaper; expanded customer service coverage; itiseasier <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Ministry of Finance to identify <strong>the</strong>origins and <strong>the</strong> destination of payments; and lesstime spent in tax compliance.Egypt established a Model Tax and CustomsCentre in 2003. The Centre has brought toge<strong>the</strong>r<strong>the</strong> three revenue generating departments in onebuilding with one tax and customs file <strong>for</strong> everytax payer. Efficiency in collection and avoidanceof double taxation were evident in tax with payers’compliance with <strong>the</strong> new system.6. Establish a flat tax and cut back special exemptionsand privileges:Estonia: 1994 re<strong>for</strong>m replaced a concessionladensystem with a single flat tax offering noexemption. The country’s tax base broadened,and revenues have not suffered.Slovakia: in 2003 streamlined its convolutedincentive schemes into a single flat tax, withsimilar results.Colombia, El Salvador, Indonesia, Jamaica ,andMexico: eliminated distortions by cutting ineffectiveincentive schemes — and increased revenuesin <strong>the</strong> process.7. Increase revenue by keeping rate moderate:Russia: reduced corporate tax rate from 35percent to 24 percent in 2001, resulting in anannual average revenue growth of 14 percent over<strong>the</strong> next three years, <strong>the</strong> lower rate resulted inincreased tax compliance.Egypt: reduced <strong>the</strong> corporate tax rate from 40percent to 20 percent in 2005. Indications showthat <strong>the</strong>re is an increase in tax compliance.248


Expansion1. Distribute both positive and negative credit in<strong>for</strong>mationin <strong>the</strong> registry sharing credit in<strong>for</strong>mation:There is a need to put more emphasis on positivein<strong>for</strong>mation like outstanding loans, assets, landpayment behaviour on accounts in good standing.The public registries in Belgium, Brazil, andTurkey began sharing more positive in<strong>for</strong>mation.Backed by new laws, <strong>the</strong> Greek and Hong Kongprivate bureaus did <strong>the</strong> same. In Greece, <strong>the</strong>number of bureau consultations grew by morethan 50 percent and several new products <strong>for</strong>lenders were launched. In addition, negativein<strong>for</strong>mation like defaults and arrears should alsobe displayed.2. Improve data quality (re<strong>for</strong>ms on registries):Bangladesh: <strong>the</strong> public registry raised <strong>the</strong> penalty<strong>for</strong> banks that withhold data from 2,000 takasto 500,000 takas and <strong>the</strong> penalty <strong>for</strong> disclosingcredit in<strong>for</strong>mation to unauthorised parties from2,000 takas to 100,000 takas. As a result, <strong>the</strong>share of banks submitting data on time jumpedfrom 25 percent to 95 percent.Mozambique: quality shot up after new regulationsallowed <strong>the</strong> registry to fine banks <strong>for</strong>providing incomplete in<strong>for</strong>mation. More than adozen countries are improving data protectionlaws, which include incentives and safeguards <strong>for</strong>quality.3. Make credit registry electronic:Pakistan: an online system has been implementedto improve credit registries. Providingonline access is associated with more credit. Inaddition, this system might help spur commercialbanks to adopt credit-scoring technology, whichboth speeds up <strong>the</strong> lending process and reducesopportunities <strong>for</strong> gender bias. Creditors can nowobtain in<strong>for</strong>mation instantly.4. Introduce universal security <strong>for</strong> debtors andcreditors:Slovakia permitted debtors to use all movable assetsas collateral — present and future, tangibleand intangible, and abolished <strong>the</strong> requirements<strong>for</strong> specific description of assets and debts. Since<strong>the</strong>n, movables and receivables secure more than70 percent of all new business credit.5. Permit out of court collateral en<strong>for</strong>cement:Spain: introduced out of court en<strong>for</strong>cementthrough notaries execution, allowing debtors andcreditors to agree on en<strong>for</strong>cement methods. Timeto en<strong>for</strong>ce was cut from more than one year tothree months.Slovakia: <strong>the</strong> gains from re<strong>for</strong>ms were even larger.It took 560 days to en<strong>for</strong>ce a mortgage through<strong>the</strong> old system. Now it is possible to en<strong>for</strong>ce it in45 days.India: state-owned banks which account <strong>for</strong> 90percent of lending, were permitted to en<strong>for</strong>cesettlement out of court. On default <strong>the</strong> bank mustnotify <strong>the</strong> debtor. After a 60-day grace period<strong>the</strong> bank can seize <strong>the</strong> assets directly and sell bypublic auction. Creditors can expect to en<strong>for</strong>cewithin nine months.Ukraine also expanded <strong>the</strong> scope of assets thatcan be used as collateral, and gave secured creditorsfirst priority to <strong>the</strong>ir collateral and its proceeds.In addition, it gave creditors <strong>the</strong> ability toen<strong>for</strong>ce collateral privately, bypassing <strong>the</strong> lengthycourt procedures required be<strong>for</strong>e.Croatia cut several months from en<strong>for</strong>cement bymaking it harder <strong>for</strong> debtors to delay <strong>the</strong> en<strong>for</strong>cementprocess. Movable collateral can now beseized and sold not just by <strong>the</strong> courts but also byauthorised private firms.Poland changed its bankruptcy laws in 2003.Previously, employees and taxes were paid be<strong>for</strong>e<strong>the</strong> secured creditors upon liquidation. Now, se-249


cured creditors have priority to <strong>the</strong> proceeds from<strong>the</strong> sale of <strong>the</strong>ir collateral.Armenia: since March 2004, <strong>the</strong> debtor automaticallyloses control of his or her property to anadministrator on bankruptcy, increasing creditorrights.6. Introduce a new Leasing law:The development of leasing as a complementarytool to bank loans provides an alternative solution,which can significantly expand access tocapital <strong>for</strong> business.Benefits are: (a) an effective tool where capitalmarkets are less developed; (b) security arrangementsare simpler as it is provided by <strong>the</strong> leasedasset itself; (c) little cash is required, allowing<strong>the</strong> lessee to conserve cash or use it as w<strong>ork</strong>ingcapital; (d) tax incentives often make it possible<strong>for</strong> SMEs to reduce income be<strong>for</strong>e taxes; and(e) promotes investment in capital equipment,increases competition in <strong>the</strong> financial sector, andfacilitates <strong>the</strong> transfer of new technology.Serbia and Montenegro: since passing a new leasinglaw in May 2003, nine new leasing companieshave opened <strong>for</strong> business. They expect toissue US$170 million in leases this year, roughlyhalf of all SME finance in <strong>the</strong> country.Uzbekistan: <strong>the</strong> level of leasing transactions wasextremely small, now <strong>the</strong>re are 23 leasing companiesfinancing SMEs.Kazakhstan: after amending <strong>the</strong> tax law in 2003,six new lessors opened: leasing deals grew fromUS$57 million to US$89 million within threemonths of <strong>the</strong> introduction of <strong>the</strong> new legislation,and <strong>the</strong> average deal size fell from US$190,000to under US$90,000, bringing leasing withinreach of more SMEs.Egypt: lease law introduced in 2000. Seven leasingcompanies cover most sectoral activities andmore than $5 billion of financial leasing activitieswere introduced in <strong>the</strong> financial market.7. Repeal <strong>the</strong> normative acts, which authorisebanks to carry out functions that are not appropriate<strong>for</strong> financial intermediaries:Uzbekistan: banks act regularly as tax agents totrack timely tax payments and o<strong>the</strong>r mandatoryreturns by SMEs and to withdraw <strong>the</strong> outstandingamount of taxes and o<strong>the</strong>r payments owed to<strong>the</strong> authority. Obviously, SMEs do not view banksas effective financial intermediaries. As a result,<strong>the</strong>re is a need to repeal <strong>the</strong> normative acts,which authorise banks to carry out functions, thatare not appropriate.En<strong>for</strong>cing Contracts1. Summary proceedings:Russia: <strong>the</strong> most popular re<strong>for</strong>m in 2003 was <strong>the</strong>introduction of summary proceedings <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> collectionof small debt and o<strong>the</strong>r smaller commercialdisputes. In late 2002, 60 percent of debtcollection cases in Moscow used this procedure.A summary procedure typically takes two monthsfrom start to finish, nine months less than a generalprocedure.2. Introducing case management:Case management can be described as a procedurein which <strong>the</strong> judge follows <strong>the</strong> case fromstart to end, reduces delays and increases usersatisfaction. In addition, this is very important <strong>for</strong>collection of debt. The average duration of debtcollection is five months in rich countries wherejudges actively manage <strong>the</strong> case, and nearly 18months in rich countries where judges don’t.Finland: an electronic system of recording waspart of <strong>the</strong> case management. A judge can followeach case at any moment, reducing <strong>the</strong> time ittakes to reach resolution.Slovakia: this system has been implemented250


successfully without much additional cost. Theaverage time between filing and <strong>the</strong> first hearingwas cut from 73 days to 27 and <strong>the</strong> averagenumber of procedures from 23 to five, as judgeswere randomly assigned and could schedule <strong>the</strong>hearings without <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> consultation withcourt clerks and o<strong>the</strong>r judges.3. Privatise en<strong>for</strong>cement process and make itcompetitive:Private en<strong>for</strong>cement or specialised public collectionagencies to collect debt are more effective.The best way to speed <strong>the</strong> recovery of overdue debtis by allowing competition in en<strong>for</strong>cing judgments.Colombia scrapped <strong>the</strong> monopoly of <strong>the</strong> courts toen<strong>for</strong>ce judge’s ruling in 2003. Private companiesquickly moved into <strong>the</strong> business. As a result,time was cut by nearly two months.Hungary and Slovakia also introduced privateen<strong>for</strong>cement.ExitWith higher recovery rates, banks are more willingto lend and more money goes to new businessventures. The freedom to take on new ventures,and do so through an efficient process, ensuresthat a country’s people and capital are put to<strong>the</strong>ir most productive uses.1. Specialised expertise:Provide specialised judges who deal with <strong>for</strong>eclosureor bankruptcy cases. In developing countriesthis can be achieved by establishing a specializedcommercial section in <strong>the</strong> general court or in anadministrative agency.Peru: Its clerks and judges deal only with bankruptcyand debt recovery issues and not withdivorce or criminal cases.2. Limit appeals:Appeals are needed to resolve legitimate disputes.But too often <strong>the</strong>y are abused and invoked<strong>for</strong> frivolous reasons thus delaying an efficientoutcome. Limiting appeals, both at <strong>the</strong> outsetand during <strong>the</strong> procedure, increases recoveryrates.Australia, New Zealand and <strong>the</strong> United Kingdom:In <strong>for</strong>eclosure proceedings, <strong>the</strong> creditors needonly to prove that a payment is overdue. Appeal isnot possible.El Salvador: in contrast, <strong>the</strong> debtor can appeal<strong>for</strong>eclosure and delay its start by up to 16 months.Appeals delay liquidation or reorganisation.Romania reduced each appeal from 30 to 10days. In addition, appeal can be limited only onlegal grounds, not on <strong>the</strong> case facts, which arealready established and accepted by <strong>the</strong> judge at<strong>the</strong> start of <strong>the</strong> case.Estonia: allows <strong>the</strong> case to continue duringappeal, avoiding disruption while providing <strong>for</strong>disputes to be resolved. Allowing <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>eclosureor bankruptcy case to continue on appeal is associatedwith 20 percent less time in closing abusiness. And it almost doubles <strong>the</strong> chance ofkeeping it operating.Successful Initiatives taken by BusinessesThis section focuses on <strong>the</strong> initiatives taken from<strong>the</strong> private sector including in<strong>for</strong>mal businessesperspectives on <strong>the</strong>ir business rights and ensure<strong>the</strong>y can take full advantage of opportunities andmarkets.1. Appropriate legal framew<strong>ork</strong>s that enshrine <strong>the</strong>following as economic rights:• Access to finance, raw material, and productmarkets at fair prices;• Access to transport and communication infrastructure;251


• Access to improved skills and technology;• Access to business development services;• Access to business incentive and trade promotionpackages: tax deferrals, subsidies, tradefairs, etc.;Examples:Fair Trade examplesVegcare, KenyaGrameen Bank, BangladeshSocial Fund, Egypt2. Legal property rights:• Private land• Intellectual property• Examples:land rights <strong>for</strong> rural women in Mozambique, intellectualproperty rights <strong>for</strong> indigenous peoplein sou<strong>the</strong>rn Africa3. Use rights to public resources and appropriatezoning regulations:• Rights to urban public land;• Rights to common and public resources: pastures,<strong>for</strong>ests, and waterways;• Appropriate zoning regulations stipulatingwhere and under what conditions in<strong>for</strong>maloperators or businesses can operate in centralbusiness districts, suburban areas, and/orindustrial zonesExamples:Warwick Junction in Durban/eThekwini;Dedicated Built Market <strong>for</strong> Traditional MedicineVendors in Durban/eThekwini, SouthAfrica;Buy-Back Centre <strong>for</strong> Waste Collectors in Durban/eThekwini,South Africa;street vendors zoning in Bangkok and Manila.4. Appropriate legal framew<strong>ork</strong>s and standards<strong>for</strong> what in<strong>for</strong>mal operators and businesses areallowed to buy and sell:• Appropriate laws and regulations on what arelegal vs. illegal goods and services;• Appropriate product and process standards:e.g., public health and sanitation concernsabout street food;• Marketing licenses <strong>for</strong> products and servicesExamples:Appropriate standards <strong>for</strong> handling and processingof milk in Nicaragua, Kenya;market license <strong>for</strong> gum collectors in India.5. Appropriate legal tools to govern <strong>the</strong> transactionand contractual relationships of in<strong>for</strong>maloperators or businesses:• Bargaining and negotiating mechanisms/power;• Legal and en<strong>for</strong>ceable contracts;• Grievance mechanisms;• Conflict resolution mechanisms;• Possibility of issuing shares;• Right to issue shares;• Right to advertise and protect brands andtrademarks;Examples:Brand name and advertisement <strong>for</strong> packagedcashew nuts in Senegal;brand name and fair prices <strong>for</strong> Ghanaianchocolate in UK;use of IT to market fish products in Senegal,India.6. Legal rights and mechanisms to provide in<strong>for</strong>maloperators and businesses with:• Temporary unemployment relief• Insurance of various kinds, including of land,house, equipment, and o<strong>the</strong>r means ofproduction;• Bankruptcy rules;• Default rules;• Limited liability;252


• Asset protection;• Capital protection;• Capital withdrawal and transfer rules.Examples:Limited liability devices (ILD);Asset shielding devices (ILD; )Capital locking-in devices (ILD).7. Legal right <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal operators and businessesto join or <strong>for</strong>m organisations, legal recognitionof such organisations, and legal right ofrepresentation of such organisations in relevantpolicy- making and rule-setting institutions:• Membership in mainstream business associations;• Membership in guilds or o<strong>the</strong>r associations ofsimilar types of entrepreneurs;• Representation in relevant planning and rulesettingbodies.Examples:SEWA in India;StreetNet International;Ghana Trades Union Congress;Catalunya affiliate of national trade union confederationin Spain.An Integrated Economy ApproachInstead of considering <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>maleconomies as a dichotomy, practice is beginningto recognise <strong>the</strong>m as a continuum. Slowly butsurely, <strong>the</strong> more enlightened policymakers arebeginning to understand that legal empowermentin <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of reduced regulatory burden makessound business sense. New models, some of whichhave been illustrated above, are emerging whichrecognise that economic policy has to promotean integrated approach to maximise social andeconomic opportunity and well-being of all socialand economic strata. The integrated and inclusiveeconomy approach recognises that if relationshipsbetween different levels of economic activity areto be anticipated, and made strategic and optimal,policy and institutional change <strong>for</strong> sustained businesslinkages and skills development has to takeplace.To design and support <strong>the</strong> development of appropriatepolicy and institutions <strong>for</strong> an integratedeconomy, innovations emerging at <strong>the</strong> interfacebetween <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal and <strong>for</strong>mal have to beanalysed. Small producers and micro entrepreneursare daily developing strategies <strong>for</strong> dealingwith <strong>the</strong> demands of <strong>for</strong>mal institutions while<strong>the</strong> latter have also developed ways of managing<strong>the</strong>ir inevitable encounter with those who are<strong>the</strong> majority in <strong>the</strong> poorer countries of <strong>the</strong> world.These coping strategies hold <strong>the</strong> clues to whatdevelopment interventions can build upon withinparticular cultures and economies.Analysis of current practice offers several observationsthat could guide movement froma bifurcated to an integrated, cohesive approachto entrepreneurship and economic activity.First, in order to encourage greater engagementbetween established <strong>for</strong>mal businesses and <strong>the</strong>smaller enterprises, transaction costs and risks ofsuch engagement have to be reduced.Second, <strong>the</strong> public sector has to develop andimplement participatory processes so that supportis relevant to those on <strong>the</strong> fringes of <strong>for</strong>mal activity.Third, change has to be negotiated throughiterative dialogue and partnerships that spanacross central and local governments, <strong>the</strong> privatesector, domestic capital markets, producer groupsand <strong>the</strong>ir social and economic organisations.Fourth, <strong>the</strong> function in micro and small scaleentrepreneurial activity of ‘immediate and directreciprocities’ 94 has to be recognised; in many lowincomecommunities social groups and economic253


Case Study:Identity, Voice, and Association in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy— The Long Journey of Self-employed Women’s Association (Sewa), IndiaSEWA, established in 1972, is a trade unionof low-income w<strong>ork</strong>ing women who earn <strong>the</strong>irlivelihoods by running small businesses, doingsubcontracting w<strong>ork</strong> or selling <strong>the</strong>ir labour.With over 700,000 members in 2003, SEWA is<strong>the</strong> first trade union of w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy not only in India, but also around <strong>the</strong>world. It is also <strong>the</strong> largest trade union in India.SEWA’s objectives are to increase self—relianceas well as <strong>the</strong> economic and social securityof its members. SEWA members fall into fourbroad occupational categories:• Hawkers and vendors, who sell a range of productsincluding vegetables, fruit and used clothingfrom baskets, push carts or small shops;• Home-based producers, who stitch garments,make patchw<strong>ork</strong> quilts, roll hand-made cigarettes(bidis) or incense sticks, prepare snackfoods, recycle scrap metal, process agriculturalproducts, produce pottery or make craft items;• Manual labourers and service providers, whosell <strong>the</strong>ir labour (as cart-pullers, head-loadersor construction w<strong>ork</strong>ers), or who sell services(such as waste-paper picking, laundry servicesor domestic services); and• Rural producers, including small farmers,milk producers, animal rearers, nursery raisers/tenders, salt farmers and gum collectors.Over <strong>the</strong> years, SEWA has built a sisterhood ofinstitutions, as follows:• SEWA Union (<strong>the</strong> primary membership-basedorganisation to which all SEWA members belongand which provides overall governance of<strong>the</strong> organisation);• SEWA Bank (which provides financial services,including both savings and credit);• Gujarat Mahila Cooperative Federation (whichis responsible <strong>for</strong> organising and supportingSEWA’s membership in several types of co-operatives);• Gujarat Mahila Housing SEWA Trust (whichprovides housing services);• SEWA Social Security (which provides health,childcare and insurance services);• Rural and Urban Branches of SEWA (whichoversee, respectively, its rural and urban activities,including <strong>the</strong> recruitment and organisingof members);• SEWA Marketing (which provides productdevelopment and marketing services);• SEWA Academy (which is responsible <strong>for</strong>research, training, and communication).The first three are democratic membershipbasedorganisations, governed by elected representatives.The o<strong>the</strong>rs are support institutionsthat provide services of various kinds to SEWAmembers. Source: SEWA, 2003.groups are synonymous. How social relationsand values o<strong>the</strong>r than material affect <strong>the</strong> modusoperandi of millions of entrepreneurs has to bebrought into economic re<strong>for</strong>m considerations.Finally, <strong>the</strong> private sector has to be defined asincorporating all entrepreneurial activity in anycountry and should be seen as inclusive of both‘entrepreneurship inspired by opportunity’ and254


‘entrepreneurship inspired by necessity’. 95 Thelatter was always known as <strong>the</strong> social welfareapproach; it now needs to be looked at througha business and wealth creation lens. Within aninclusive economy, entrepreneurship, whe<strong>the</strong>r<strong>for</strong>mal or in<strong>for</strong>mal, would be supported by:• Removal of regulations that unduly inhibitprivate sector development;• An integrated perspective on micro, small,medium and large enterprises;• Linkages between various sizes of businesses;• Increased efficiency and productivity of <strong>the</strong>labour <strong>for</strong>ce;• Enhanced competition;• Expanded markets. 96In making profitable markets more inclusive of<strong>the</strong> poor, risk mediation is a fundamental concern.Formal institutions and large firms as wellas small and micro enterprises are all equally riskaverse, given <strong>the</strong> absence of adequate investorprotection or social safety nets in many countries.Acceptable risk is central in developing andsustaining trust. 97 So far, successful mediationbetween large and small businesses has usuallybeen provided by guarantees through contractualand financial arrangements facilitated by credibleintermediaries such as donors, governments andNGOs. These models can be scaled up to becomemainstream if <strong>the</strong>re is political will towards propoorpolicy and institutions that can move currentpractice towards greater parity and fairness inaccess to opportunity and assets.sector, in <strong>the</strong> national economy. These corporateentities of micro-enterprises can become <strong>the</strong>natural partners of larger corporate entities thatmight outsource many of <strong>the</strong>ir operations andcomponent inputs to <strong>the</strong>se entities. The problemsof dealing with large numbers of such enterprises,scattered as <strong>the</strong>y are across <strong>the</strong> country,and maintaining quality control have discouragedwhat might o<strong>the</strong>rwise have been a mostcost-effective partnership between <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>maland in<strong>for</strong>mal sector. Larger corporate entities ofmicro-enterprises would eliminate both <strong>the</strong> costand managerial problems associated with buildingthis linkage and could open new horizons ofopportunity that might lead <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sectorto become <strong>for</strong>mally integrated with <strong>the</strong> macroeconomy.98To Sum UpThere are rich, real life examples of ‘businessrights’ successes from all over <strong>the</strong> world that canbe borrowed and implemented, with necessary improvementsand modifications to suit local environmentsand priorities. What is needed on <strong>the</strong> partof both <strong>the</strong> authorities and business participantsis openness in critically evaluating real-life cases,and in adopting and adapting as necessary thosewith potential <strong>for</strong> successful implementation.Ano<strong>the</strong>r example of integration is <strong>the</strong> prospect oflarge numbers of micro-enterprises, living precariouslives in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector, coming toge<strong>the</strong>rto <strong>for</strong>m large corporate entities, and competing innational and global markets. This could providea new perspective on <strong>the</strong> role of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal255


6. Pursuing <strong>the</strong> agenda <strong>for</strong>changeOver <strong>the</strong> last two decades, much attention hasbeen paid to legal and regulatory institutions andto <strong>the</strong>ir influence on economic outcomes. It isrecognition of <strong>the</strong> importance of good governancein advancing economic development initiatives.As a result, much development assistance isbeing directed towards re<strong>for</strong>ms of national legalcodes, public institutions, and bureaucraticprocesses. The anticipated result is a legalinfrastructure conducive to market-led economicgrowth. However, <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m movement has notfully (perhaps only marginally) addressed <strong>the</strong>multifarious issues of in<strong>for</strong>mal economic activity.Deregulation was expected to result in significantshifts of entrepreneurial activity from in<strong>for</strong>malto <strong>for</strong>mal. But, as pointed out earlier <strong>the</strong> scaleof in<strong>for</strong>mal economic activity is actually growing,not decreasing. The in<strong>for</strong>mal sector is hereto stay. At <strong>the</strong> same time, policy re<strong>for</strong>m, thatstreng<strong>the</strong>ns what w<strong>ork</strong>s <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor andresponds to what does not, is long overdue.<strong>Law</strong>s, regulations, and institutions governingcommercial relations need to reflect <strong>the</strong> realitythat most economic units are very small with fewhired w<strong>ork</strong>ers and that many of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing pooroperate on <strong>the</strong>ir own account. Also, biases inexisting laws, regulations, and institutions thatfavour large enterprises over small ones, and menover women, need to be addressed. Meanwhile,in <strong>the</strong> absence of new and more appropriate laws,regulations and institutions, most in<strong>for</strong>mal businesseswill remain unprotected, insecure, andvulnerable.Business-related re<strong>for</strong>ms are now really comingunder closer scruitiny. 99 In fact, <strong>the</strong>re is anincreasing demand <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms to contain ‘valuebased policies, strategies and institutions’ thatwill bring long-term sustainable benefits to <strong>the</strong>poor in general and to in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises inparticular.What is needed at this juncture are policiesregarding <strong>for</strong>malisation that not only simplify<strong>for</strong>malities or improve <strong>the</strong> quality of regulation,but also increase <strong>the</strong> value of in<strong>for</strong>mationprovided by public registers to <strong>the</strong>ir users, bothpublic and private. This is because business <strong>for</strong>malisationis an ordinary productive process thatincurs costs but also provides valuable publicand private services. The private services reducefirms’ transaction costs in many of <strong>the</strong>ir contracts,and <strong>the</strong> public services facilitate <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>of <strong>the</strong> administration in its dealings with firms.In o<strong>the</strong>r words, ‘<strong>the</strong> main priority should not beto reduce <strong>the</strong> cost of business <strong>for</strong>malisation — acost paid only once — but ra<strong>the</strong>r to reduce transactioncosts in all business dealings. . . . Therestructuring of <strong>for</strong>malities is in itself insufficient<strong>for</strong> reducing total transaction costs. It may alsobe a costly distraction. It is necessary, ra<strong>the</strong>r, toenhance <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>for</strong>malisation.’ 100Addressing in<strong>for</strong>mality, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, is a multi-facetedproposition requiring a thorough understandingof <strong>the</strong> factors that create and drive in<strong>for</strong>mality.Re<strong>for</strong>m initiatives may also require that <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mal sector be re-defined to accommodatemany of <strong>the</strong> principles and values which characterise<strong>the</strong> vibrancy and resilience of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malsector. Clearly, <strong>the</strong>re is no single approach tore<strong>for</strong>m but <strong>the</strong>re are essential and common principlesthat must be observed. Three key ones are:context specificity, a participatory and genderedapproach, and recognition of legal empowermentof in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses as a governance issue.This section sums up our discussion on what <strong>the</strong>promise of legal empowerment holds with respectto unlocking <strong>the</strong> productive capacities of <strong>the</strong>256


millions who operate poor, micro in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses.Changes have to be Context SpecificAlthough development interventions tend to favourre<strong>for</strong>m through standardised, ‘best practice’ institutional<strong>for</strong>ms, 101 what is required is an empiricallygrounded perspective using context-specificresearch, organisational innovation and politicalentrepreneurship ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> importation ofinstitutional templates (‘toolkits’) <strong>for</strong>ged elsewhere.102 Because rules are at once constituentelements of cultural norms and values as muchas <strong>the</strong>y are embodied in commercial codes andconstitutions, attempts at ‘legal empowerment’need to engage if not with that full spectrum <strong>the</strong>nat least with a more complete awareness of <strong>the</strong>spectrum’s existence and importance. 103There<strong>for</strong>e context-specificity is a fundamentalrequirement in moving towards change. Thisspecificity must also extend to <strong>the</strong> reality ofdifferent categories of in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses inspecific locales and industries. Any policy orinstitutional re<strong>for</strong>m has to recognise and supportboth <strong>the</strong> self-employed (differentiating betweenmicro-entrepreneurs and own-account operators)and wage w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. Thelack of recognition and understanding of <strong>the</strong>sebasic components of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy oftenhinders <strong>the</strong> development of appropriate policy.Re<strong>for</strong>m Processes Must beParticipatory and Gender ResponsivePolicy and institutional re<strong>for</strong>m should be participatoryand inclusive and allow <strong>for</strong> policies tobe developed through consultation with in<strong>for</strong>malbusinesses, and through consensus of relevantgovernment departments, <strong>the</strong> organisations ofin<strong>for</strong>mal businesses and o<strong>the</strong>r appropriate socialactors. In order to have a voice, those who arein <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy must be organised and<strong>the</strong>ir ef<strong>for</strong>ts to organise into association andcooperatives at every level should be encouraged.In order to organise, <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor have to beallowed <strong>the</strong> space and resources to associate <strong>for</strong>a common economic purpose and without politicalmanipulation.Of course, <strong>for</strong>mulating appropriate policies andstrategies is not an easy task. However, with <strong>the</strong>involvement of <strong>the</strong> organisations that representin<strong>for</strong>mal businesses it is likely to succeed. Theway <strong>for</strong>ward has to be one of negotiated solutions,and <strong>the</strong>se negotiations have to be aboutrights and responsibilities. While <strong>the</strong> inclusionof <strong>the</strong> voice of all stakeholders in making policyis essential to its success, <strong>the</strong> input of in<strong>for</strong>malw<strong>ork</strong>ers and <strong>the</strong>ir organisations, based on recognitionof <strong>the</strong>ir right to organise, is crucial.The voice of women has to be clearly heard inthis process. In most regions of <strong>the</strong> world, alarger share of <strong>the</strong> female than of <strong>the</strong> male w<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong>ceis in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy and, within <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, more women tend to be concentratedin lower-return segments than are men.As a result, even within <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy,<strong>the</strong>re is a significant gender gap in earnings andin <strong>the</strong> benefits and protection af<strong>for</strong>ded by w<strong>ork</strong>.Understanding relations between men and women,<strong>the</strong>ir different positions in <strong>the</strong> economy and<strong>the</strong>ir access to and control of resources, is crucialto understanding <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, wherea gendered approach is a pro-poor approach.Supporting women’s w<strong>ork</strong> will, in effect, lead tosupport <strong>for</strong> poor households and poor children.Legal empowerment of in<strong>for</strong>malbusiness should be prioritised as agovernance issueThe re<strong>for</strong>m process should be based on an in<strong>for</strong>medunderstanding of <strong>the</strong> economic contribu-257


Case Study:Technology and <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector: Fishing with Mobile PhonesA Fisherman on <strong>the</strong> coast of Kerala, in sou<strong>the</strong>rnIndia, faces <strong>the</strong> dilemma: in <strong>the</strong> situationof good catch, should he or she sell <strong>the</strong> fish(sardines) at <strong>the</strong> local beach or or travel to amarket far<strong>the</strong>r away? If he or she stays at <strong>the</strong>local beach , prices could be low due to oversupply, but travelling would be a costly decisionin terms of transportation cost and time toano<strong>the</strong>r market. Moreover, each market remainsopen <strong>for</strong> only a couple of hours be<strong>for</strong>e dawn andfish are perishable; any that cannot be sold willhave to be dumped into <strong>the</strong> sea.According to a research by Robert Jensen, until<strong>the</strong> introduction of mobiles phones in 1997 fishepeople used to stick with <strong>the</strong>ir home marketsall <strong>the</strong> time. This was wasteful: on average, 5-8percent of <strong>the</strong> total catch was lost. He noted, <strong>for</strong>example, on January 14th 1997, ‘Eleven fishermenat Badagara beach ended up throwing away<strong>the</strong>ir catches, yet on that day <strong>the</strong>re were 27 buyersat markets within 15km (about nine miles)who would have bought <strong>the</strong>ir fish.’After <strong>the</strong> introduction of mobile phones <strong>the</strong>rewas remarkable change in fishermen’s behaviour,<strong>the</strong> price of fish, and <strong>the</strong> amount of waste.Fishermen started to buy phones and use <strong>the</strong>mto call coastal markets while still at sea. Insteadof selling <strong>the</strong>ir fish at home beach auctions, <strong>the</strong>fishermen would call around to find <strong>the</strong> bestprice. In one area, <strong>the</strong> proportion of fishermenwho ventured beyond <strong>the</strong>ir home markets to sell<strong>the</strong>ir catches jumped from zero to around 35percent. At that point, no fish were wasted and<strong>the</strong> variation in prices fell dramatically. ‘The‘law of one price’ — <strong>the</strong> idea that in efficientmarket identical goods should cost <strong>the</strong> same— had come into effect, in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of a singlerate <strong>for</strong> sardines along <strong>the</strong> coast... This moreefficient market benefited everyone. Fishermen’sprofits rose by 8 percent on average andconsumer prices fell by 4 percent on average.Higher profits meant <strong>the</strong> phones typically paid<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>mselves within two months. And <strong>the</strong> benefitsare enduring, ra<strong>the</strong>r than one-off.’This shows <strong>the</strong> importance of <strong>the</strong> free flow ofin<strong>for</strong>mation to ensure that markets w<strong>ork</strong> efficiently,which in turn improve welfare.tion of in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses and serve to mainstream<strong>the</strong> concerns of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal businessesin those institutions that deal with economicplanning and development. In <strong>the</strong> past, <strong>the</strong>management or regulation of in<strong>for</strong>mal activitieshas often been relegated to social policy departmentsor, in urban areas, to those departments(such as <strong>the</strong> police or traffic) that deal with lawand order issues. Locating governance of <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy in traffic, health, policy orsocial departments ignores its economic aspects.Institutions that govern <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economyshould be those dealing with economic planningand development. That is why this report hasemphasised that re<strong>for</strong>m has to be couched withinan integrated economy approach where in<strong>for</strong>maland <strong>for</strong>mal are seen as equally important economicplayers, each demanding equal attentionin national governance laws and institutions.Strategies and Institutions to SupportIn<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses258


In developing and promoting new approaches,some considerations and innovations outlinedbelow could be considered. 104Market-based institutions <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poorThe capacity of in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses to operate onmore equal terms in <strong>the</strong> market place dependsgreatly on <strong>the</strong>ir capacity <strong>for</strong> collective action.The weakness of <strong>the</strong> poor in <strong>the</strong> market placeoriginates in <strong>the</strong>ir isolation. Here, investmentsin institutions, whe<strong>the</strong>r sponsored by NGOs orrepresenting collective action by <strong>the</strong> poor in <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>m of marketing cooperatives, or corporate bodiesof <strong>the</strong> poor, remain crucial interventions. Theissue <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e remains, posed as a challenge: toinvest <strong>the</strong> poor and in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses with capacityto develop <strong>the</strong> financial and organisationalstrength to sell products and services, at a timeand in a market that offers <strong>the</strong>m <strong>the</strong> best terms,or to simply watch as <strong>the</strong>y continue to sell <strong>the</strong>irgoods out of distress or just <strong>the</strong> need to subsist.Taking up <strong>the</strong> challenge positively demandsinterventions in <strong>the</strong> macro-credit market to underwritesuch marketing ventures, <strong>the</strong> designingof institutions which aggregate <strong>the</strong> market powerof <strong>the</strong> poor, and <strong>the</strong> deployment of professionalswith management skills and especially trained toassist <strong>the</strong> poor in up-scaling <strong>the</strong>ir participation in<strong>the</strong> market economy.Adding value and supply chain to <strong>the</strong> labour of <strong>the</strong>poor and in<strong>for</strong>mal businessesMany NGOs around <strong>the</strong> world provide marketingservices to <strong>the</strong> poor, <strong>for</strong> particular commodities,in particular markets. The best service that canbe provided is to help <strong>the</strong> poor and in<strong>for</strong>mal businessesadd value to <strong>the</strong>ir labours by moving upmarketthrough ei<strong>the</strong>r agro-processing or providinginputs to <strong>the</strong> corporate sector. The pioneeringrole of Amul Dairy in India and, more recently,BRAC, are instructive model examples. They enablesmall dairy farmers, or just poor householdsthat own a cow bought through a micro-creditloan, to become part of a milk processing chain,thus enabling <strong>the</strong> poor to share in <strong>the</strong> profits fromselling pasteurised milk or cheese in <strong>the</strong> metropolitanmarket. Such initiatives may be taken onestep fur<strong>the</strong>r by financially empowering <strong>the</strong> vastbody of small farmers servicing <strong>the</strong> private agroprocessingsector, as well as handloom weavers,to become equity stakeholders in <strong>the</strong> upstreamenterprises that could add value to <strong>the</strong>ir produceor abour.Taking micro-credit out of <strong>the</strong>ghetto 105Nowhere is <strong>the</strong>re a greater need <strong>for</strong> developing amacro-perspective <strong>for</strong> poverty eradication than in<strong>the</strong> area of monetary policy. The instruments ofmonetary policy appear to be exclusively targetedtowards ensuring macroeconomic stability, moderatinginflation and meeting <strong>the</strong> credit needs of<strong>the</strong> corporate sector. The financial needs of <strong>the</strong>poor, once left to <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector, have nowbeen segregated in <strong>the</strong> micro-credit market. Thisapar<strong>the</strong>id within <strong>the</strong> monetary system remains amajor anomaly.Indeed, it can however be argued that by its verynature, micro-credit can never aspire to eradicatepoverty since it only addresses one componentof <strong>the</strong> various markets that condition <strong>the</strong> lives of<strong>the</strong> rural poor. It is arguable that by locking <strong>the</strong>poor into <strong>the</strong> micro-credit system, based on <strong>the</strong>fiduciary responsibility of <strong>the</strong> household, <strong>the</strong>yhave been excluded from participating in <strong>the</strong>macro economy, isolated from collective action,and condemned to live on <strong>the</strong> fringes of <strong>the</strong> povertyline. It is, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, not surprising that thosecountries with <strong>the</strong> most substantive exposure tomicro-credit, remain mired in poverty. However, it259


is not <strong>the</strong> aim to diminish <strong>the</strong> enormous contributionof micro-credit in alleviating poverty and distress,as well as enhancing <strong>the</strong> self-worth of <strong>the</strong>poor. There is, today, no reason why such organisations,of <strong>the</strong> maturity of Grameen Bank, shouldnot graduate into <strong>the</strong> macro finance system byaccessing <strong>the</strong> deposits of <strong>the</strong> public and evenmarketing its assets at <strong>the</strong> global level, throughsuch financial instruments as securitisation, thatare in widespread use in more advanced financialsystems.Anumber of commercial banks are alreadyusing NGOs and community-based organisationsto retail banking services to <strong>the</strong> poor. O<strong>the</strong>rexamples include Scotia Bank in <strong>the</strong> Caribbeanand ANZ Bank in <strong>the</strong> Pacific Islands, which haveventured into ‘Banking <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor’ and ‘MobileBanking <strong>for</strong> Villages’. In Egypt, <strong>the</strong> Social Fund,Credit Guarantee Company and Micro-financeNGOs are not only successful providers of creditto in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses but also organisers of permanentexhibitions <strong>for</strong> MSMEs’ products, offeringentrepreneurial training and outreach services topoor enterprises.Mutual funds <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poorApart from <strong>the</strong> issue of redesigning monetarypolicy to deliver credit to <strong>the</strong> poor, <strong>the</strong> monetarysystem also needs to design special financialinstruments to attract <strong>the</strong>se micro-savings into<strong>the</strong> corporate sector, particularly where it can bestructured to serve <strong>the</strong> poor. The mutual fund isbut one institutional mechanism to link <strong>the</strong> poorto <strong>the</strong> corporate sector. The underlying premise of<strong>the</strong> mutual fund is <strong>the</strong> notion of creating possibilities<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor to own corporate assets. Opportunitiesare <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e opening <strong>for</strong> linking <strong>the</strong>farmers to <strong>the</strong> agro-processing corporate sector bygiving <strong>the</strong>m an equity stake in such enterprises.At <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong> agro-corporations shouldBox 4 Largest multi-nationalcompany has 2.3 million ruralpoor women as shareholdersThe largest single <strong>for</strong>eign corporate investment inBangladesh is manifested in <strong>the</strong> GrameenPhone experience.GrameenPhone is a commercial joint ventureto provide cellular phone services. The companycurrently has two million subscribers which coverstwo-thirds of all phone subscribers in Bangladesh.Telenor, <strong>the</strong> largest mobile phone company in Norwayholds a 51 percent ownership stake in Grameen-Phone and has so far invested over US$600 millionin <strong>the</strong> joint venture making it <strong>the</strong> largest single<strong>for</strong>eign investor in <strong>the</strong> country. Grameen Telecom,a sister organisation of Grameen Bank, ownedby 2.3 million poor rural women in Bangladesh,owns 35 percent of Grameen Phone. As and whenGrameenPhone goes public it will be possible <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong>se rural women to become direct stakeholdersin <strong>the</strong> largest private enterprise in <strong>the</strong> country. Thegoal of Grameen Bank is to make <strong>the</strong>se poor womeninto <strong>the</strong> majority owners of <strong>the</strong> company as Telenormeets <strong>the</strong>ir commitment to gradually divest <strong>the</strong>irequity stake in <strong>the</strong> company to local investors. Theprospect of poor rural women in Bangladesh owningone of <strong>the</strong> largest corporate enterprises in <strong>the</strong> countrycould have a trans<strong>for</strong>ming effect on how <strong>the</strong> poorperceive <strong>the</strong>ir role in <strong>the</strong> national economy.be motivated to invest in improving productivityand capacities of <strong>the</strong>ir rural partners. An interestingpossibility of enabling <strong>the</strong> poor to own corporateassets is provided in Bangladesh.Financial policy need not limit itself to ownershipof corporate assets but could also be restructuredto ensure that all assets, from urban land, to realestate development, and from banks to corporatetrading houses, could be redesigned to accommodate<strong>the</strong> poor as equity partners. The two260


institutional instruments to make this possibleremain <strong>the</strong> mutual fund and <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> privatelimited companies to trans<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong>mselves intopublic limited companies. Here monetary and fiscalpolicy can provide incentives to encourage <strong>the</strong>corporatisation of private wealth along with <strong>the</strong>reservation of space <strong>for</strong> equity ownership of thiswealth by <strong>the</strong> poor.Institutionalising <strong>the</strong> collectiveidentity of poor and in<strong>for</strong>malbusinesses 106Suggestions about building a collective identity<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor and in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses throughspecially constructed institutions derives from<strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor to claim a place in societythat is more commensurate with <strong>the</strong>ir numbers.The poor remain disempowered because <strong>the</strong>y areisolated; bring <strong>the</strong>m toge<strong>the</strong>r and <strong>the</strong>y emergeas a major <strong>for</strong>ce in <strong>the</strong> economy, in society and,eventually, in <strong>the</strong> political arena. Institutionalarrangements that can add value to <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>magenda are:a) Corporations of <strong>the</strong> poor and in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses:Community-based or self-help organisations(CBOs) of <strong>the</strong> poor, cooperatives andactivity-based organisations, that bring groupsof <strong>the</strong> poor toge<strong>the</strong>r, should aspire to <strong>for</strong>ge aninstitutional identity. Corporatising <strong>the</strong> CBOs willprovide <strong>the</strong> legal foundations <strong>for</strong> collective action,to enable <strong>the</strong>se bodies of <strong>the</strong> poor to accesscredit, enter into contractual relationships anddeal with international organisations. The preciselegal persona of <strong>the</strong>se corporations may varyfrom limited liability companies, with <strong>the</strong> poor asequity owners, to cooperatives with <strong>the</strong> poor aspartner members. But <strong>the</strong> common feature of allsuch corporate entities of <strong>the</strong> poor is that <strong>the</strong>ymust operate in <strong>the</strong> market place and generateincome ra<strong>the</strong>r than limiting <strong>the</strong>mselves to surviveas savings and loan associations.b) Corporatising micro-enterprises: The prospectof large numbers of micro-enterprises, livingprecarious lives in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector, comingtoge<strong>the</strong>r to <strong>for</strong>mer large corporate entities thatwould compete in national and global markets,provides a new perspective on <strong>the</strong> role of <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal sector in <strong>the</strong> national economy. Thesecorporate entities of micro-enterprises can become<strong>the</strong> natural partners of larger corporate entitiesthat could outsource many operations andcomponent inputs to <strong>the</strong>m... The larger corporateentities of micro-enterprises would eliminate both<strong>the</strong> cost and managerial problems associated withbuilding this linkage and open up new horizonsof opportunity to <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector to <strong>for</strong>mallyintegrate with <strong>the</strong> macro economy.Bangladesh provides technology upgrading,quality control, credits and marketing services tolarge numbers of handicraft enterprises across<strong>the</strong> country. However it still deals with <strong>the</strong>seenterprises as clients who are helped by accessto credit, markets and skill development. BRAChas to take <strong>the</strong> next step of aggregating <strong>the</strong>seproducers into a larger corporate entity where<strong>the</strong>y acquire an equity stake in <strong>the</strong> final profitsof <strong>the</strong> enterprise. Such a corporate entity hasbeen developed in India with <strong>the</strong> Papad cooperativewhere around 100,000 small householdenterprises producing <strong>the</strong> spicy snack condiment,<strong>the</strong> Papad, have been aggregated to become <strong>the</strong>largest single supply source of quality papads togrocery stores across <strong>the</strong> country.c) Micro-insurance — Protecting In<strong>for</strong>mal businesses:Micro-credit can help <strong>the</strong> poor rise abovepoverty. Micro-insurance can help by providingprotection against certain perils; micro-insurancecomplements o<strong>the</strong>r financial and socialservices. Because <strong>the</strong>y often live and do business261


in risky environments — in urban shanty townswith unsanitary conditions, in rural areas proneto droughts or floods — <strong>the</strong> poor and in<strong>for</strong>malbusinesses are more vulnerable than <strong>the</strong> rest of<strong>the</strong> population to perils such as illness, accidentaldeath and disability, <strong>the</strong>ft or fire, agriculturallosses, natural or manmade disasters. They arealso <strong>the</strong> least able to cope with crisis when itoccurs. Micro-insurance with <strong>the</strong> use of technologyhas been successfully been introduced in anumber of countries:In Uganda and Malawi, some insurance providersissue smart-cards to poor policyholders toconfirm that <strong>the</strong>y are who <strong>the</strong>y say <strong>the</strong>y are, andcan instantly provide in<strong>for</strong>mation on <strong>the</strong>ir level ofcoverage and whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> premium has been paid.In <strong>the</strong> Philippines, insurers have minimised <strong>the</strong>transaction costs of collecting many small premiumsby allowing people to pay via <strong>the</strong>ir mobilephones.In India, a barcode system is being tested as away of managing client in<strong>for</strong>mation. The barcodestickers are especially useful <strong>for</strong> illiterate clientswho can attach <strong>the</strong>m onto pre-addressed envelopesto identify <strong>the</strong>mselves.Business Rights — providevalue-based change process.The rationale <strong>for</strong> changes in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal businessessuch that some elements and advantagesof <strong>for</strong>malisation are incorporated is rooted in awider appreciation of how both individuals andbusinesses can be disadvantaged by operatingoutside <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy and <strong>the</strong> recognitionthat <strong>the</strong>re are benefits to <strong>for</strong>malisation. Never<strong>the</strong>lessmicro-entrepreneurs make an economiccalculation along <strong>the</strong> lines of a cost-benefitanalysis, which determines a minimum thresholdof participation in <strong>for</strong>mal arrangements <strong>for</strong> which<strong>the</strong> costs remain lower than <strong>the</strong> benefits. Somefirms will <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e choose to participate in onlya subset of institutions at any point in time. Inaddition, benefits and costs of participating in a<strong>for</strong>mal context vary <strong>for</strong> firms of different size andexpected lifetime. It would <strong>for</strong> instance seem thatyoung, inefficient and small firms are disproportionatelyin<strong>for</strong>mal.The chart below illustrates <strong>the</strong> phases an enterprisemight hypo<strong>the</strong>tically go through be<strong>for</strong>e itbecomes an official <strong>for</strong>mal enterprise. The chartalso illustrates that <strong>the</strong> transition from an in<strong>for</strong>malto a <strong>for</strong>mal status is gradual and that it isimportant to initiate <strong>the</strong> relevant processes thatcould assist enterprises to reach a more <strong>for</strong>malexistence. Any interventions in support of movingenterprises towards a more <strong>for</strong>mal existenceshould be prioritised and concentrated on where<strong>the</strong> maximum effects can be reached. The waythat <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises <strong>the</strong>mselves rank <strong>the</strong>problems that <strong>the</strong>y are facing would indicate howto prioritise interventions.In order to make a smooth transition from in<strong>for</strong>malto <strong>for</strong>mal <strong>the</strong>re needs to be a strong foundationof: a) rule of law and access to justice; b)good governance and protection of basic rights(human, legal, property and labour); c) strongphysical and social infrastructure; d) politicaland economic stability, and e) conducive and fairbusiness environment.Additionally, <strong>the</strong> causes of in<strong>for</strong>mality are complexand defy simple explanations. Consequently,<strong>the</strong> trans<strong>for</strong>mation can only be tackled successfullyby a linking set of policy initiatives thatdeliver both pull and push pressures. The DemandPull and Supply Push measures are brieflyhighlighted in Chart 1. Demand ‘Pull’ initiativesinclude: access to finance, capital and credit;tax relief and incentives, titling, public procure-262


Figure 5Legal Empowerment of In<strong>for</strong>mal EnterprisesSUPPLY PUSH• Regulatory Re<strong>for</strong>ms• Reducingadministrativebarriers• Af<strong>for</strong>dableBusiness Fees• Simplified Taxation• AccessibleBusiness Licensingand Registration• ReducingCorruption• Adaptable Labour<strong>Law</strong>sGradual Transition through Business RightsIn<strong>for</strong>malSubsistenceBusinessesUnofficialBusinessesPartlyOfficialBusinessesFormalSustainableBusinessesDEMAND PULL• Access toFinance andCredit• Tax relief andincentives• Titling• PublicProcurementOpportunities• SkillsDevelopment• EntrepreneurialtrainingRULE OF LAW& ACCESS TO JUSTICEBASIC RIGHTS(HUMAN, LEG<strong>AL</strong>,PROPERTY & LABOUR)PHYSIC<strong>AL</strong> & SOCI<strong>AL</strong>INFRASTRUCTUREPOLITIC<strong>AL</strong> & ECONOMICSTABILITY & GOODGOVERNANCECONDUCIVE &FAIR BUSINESSENVIRONMENTPILLARS OF FOUNDATION FOR FORM<strong>AL</strong>ISATIONment opportunities, skills development, entrepreneurialtraining, etc. Supply ‘Push’ initiativesare regulatory re<strong>for</strong>ms, reducing administrativebarriers, af<strong>for</strong>dable business and licensing fees,accessible business and licensing and registrationprocedures; reducing corruption; adaptablelabour laws, etc. The chart fur<strong>the</strong>r highlightsthat <strong>the</strong> number of in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises movingtowards <strong>for</strong>mal sustainable enterprises is smallcompared to <strong>the</strong> huge size of subsistence in<strong>for</strong>malenterprises.Formalisation may <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e be seen as anincremental process that begins by introducingappropriate incentives and benefits of <strong>for</strong>mality,<strong>the</strong>n progressively en<strong>for</strong>ces compliance with <strong>the</strong>costs and regulations associated with operating<strong>for</strong>mally which would depend on <strong>the</strong> size, output,or location of <strong>the</strong> enterprises. Once conditions aremet, <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economywould be entitled to <strong>the</strong> benefits of <strong>for</strong>mality and,at <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong>y would be enabled to complywith <strong>the</strong> duties of <strong>for</strong>malisationPillars of ChangeThe sustainability of any proposed re<strong>for</strong>m toa country’s governing institutions depends onpublic recognition of <strong>the</strong> changes to be made.Recognition will thus depend on <strong>the</strong> capacity of<strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m to be legitimised within <strong>the</strong> public’scultural and social milieu. Failure may prevent<strong>the</strong> successes of legal re<strong>for</strong>ms that are o<strong>the</strong>rwisecognizant of larger policy aims to promotemarket-driven economic growth. For Sub-SaharanAfrica, <strong>for</strong> example, failure to incorporate widely263


accepted customary <strong>for</strong>ms could mean outrightrejection by <strong>the</strong> private sector. There<strong>for</strong>e, indetermining what can be done to legally empowerin<strong>for</strong>mal businesses to better access <strong>the</strong> opportunities,finances, services and facilities of <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>malsector, one would have to take into accountthat which already w<strong>ork</strong>s.The recommendations of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing group <strong>for</strong>Chapter 4 of this report may be summarised indescriptions of five proposed pillars of re<strong>for</strong>m:Pillar 1: Adopt an inclusive and integratedapproach to economic development so that <strong>the</strong>reis legal recognition and empowerment of in<strong>for</strong>malbusinesses.Legally empowering small in<strong>for</strong>mal businessesrun by poor individuals or households should beseen as a central pillar of a just society and acentral strategy <strong>for</strong> reducing poverty and inequality.This means that policies and global economicprivilege, which is geared at present to <strong>the</strong> elitesand large enterprises, have to change to becomeinclusive of <strong>the</strong> billions at <strong>the</strong> bottom of <strong>the</strong> economicpyramid. These billions are <strong>the</strong> producersand consumers who make markets profitable <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> privileged. Their share has to be duly recognisedthrough much greater public and privatesector cognisance and support to small firmsand enterprises. In<strong>for</strong>mality, with its flexibilityand space <strong>for</strong> millions to engage productivelyin economies, is here to stay. Official and legalresponse needs to recognise what w<strong>ork</strong>s in thissector and streng<strong>the</strong>n and integrate <strong>the</strong>se innovationsinto an inclusive integrated approach towealth creation.Pillar 2: Support legal empowerment througha package of commercial rights underlined inpolicies and instituted and en<strong>for</strong>ced throughregulatory bodies.Commercial rights <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal entrepreneurs/operatorsinclude, but are not limited to, propertyrights, labour rights, right to social protection,right to be organised and represented in policymakingand rule-setting institutions and processes,and <strong>the</strong> right of access to justice in a transparentand equitable manner. The rights of <strong>the</strong> morevulnerable groups — <strong>the</strong> own-account operators,including single-person operators and those whow<strong>ork</strong> in family businesses or on family farms— must also be addressed. These commercialrights should address all categories of in<strong>for</strong>malenterprise, and include <strong>the</strong> following provisions:a) Basic commercial rights: right to w<strong>ork</strong>, including<strong>the</strong> right to vend; right to a w<strong>ork</strong> space(public land, private residences), includingrelated basic infrastructure (shelter, electricity,water, sanitation);b)Intermediary commercial rights: right togovernment incentives and support (includingprocurement, tax holidays, export licensing,export promotion); right to public infrastructure(transport and communication);c) Advanced commercial rights: relevant <strong>for</strong> larger,more advanced in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises.Pillar 3: Reduce Decent W<strong>ork</strong> ‘defi cits’ of thosewho w<strong>ork</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mally.This means support to in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses in <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>m of:• Participation in policy processes of a representativevoice of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy. Recognition and correction of <strong>the</strong>bias in existing commercial policies, regulations,laws and procedures favouring largerfirms and enterprises. Extension of governmentincentives and procurements to <strong>the</strong> smallestin<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises;• Facilitation as appropriate of backward and264


<strong>for</strong>ward linkages on fair terms between largerand smaller firms;• Promotion of market access and fair trade <strong>for</strong>smaller firms and enterprises;• Social protection of in<strong>for</strong>mal operators throughproperty, health, life, disability insurance;• Adequate and relevant retraining, life-longlearning, and o<strong>the</strong>r support to labour mobility.Pillar 4: Broaden access of in<strong>for</strong>mal businessto financial services and support innovation infinancial products and processes. This requiresthat <strong>the</strong>re be:• Awareness in both <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>mal creditsystems of <strong>the</strong> way <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor use creditand <strong>the</strong> barriers and often inappropriate rulesin <strong>for</strong>mal lending procedures;• Legal and administrative processes in placewhich make <strong>the</strong> processing of collateral includingsocial collateral cheaper, transparent andfaster;• Legally recognised and mutually negotiated riskmediation processes in place <strong>for</strong> both <strong>the</strong> lendersand borrowers from in<strong>for</strong>mal business;• Support to innovation in financial products andservices with a view to deepening <strong>the</strong>ir outreach.Pillar 5: Engage in evidence-based re<strong>for</strong>m.There are now hundreds of good practice examplesthat illustrate how <strong>the</strong> constraints of in<strong>for</strong>malbusinesses have been successfully addressedaround <strong>the</strong> world. These examples should bestudied and <strong>the</strong> lessons learnt should be groupedaccording to what constraint or need was beingaddressed and <strong>the</strong> policy lesson drawn from <strong>the</strong>experience. The policy re<strong>for</strong>m that ensures shouldbe participatory and targeted to <strong>the</strong> realities of <strong>the</strong>different sub-sectors in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.ConclusionsThis report has outlined how <strong>the</strong> process ofachieving greater legal empowerment (throughbusiness rights and access to <strong>the</strong> advantagesof <strong>for</strong>malisation) can and should take different<strong>for</strong>ms. Incentives to encourage in<strong>for</strong>mal entrepreneursto actively engage in <strong>the</strong> change processmust show actual benefits to <strong>the</strong>ir livelihoods and<strong>the</strong>ir well-being. These incentives are essentiallywhat would result if <strong>the</strong> barriers to entry intoand/or interaction with <strong>for</strong>mal and legal economicactivity were addressed. Incentives could be in<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of• Simplified registration procedures and progressiveregistration fees;• A supportive investment climate and a businessenabling environment;• Fair commercial transactions between in<strong>for</strong>malenterprises and <strong>for</strong>mal firms;• Appropriate legal and regulatory framew<strong>ork</strong>s,including: en<strong>for</strong>ceable commercial contracts;private property rights; more equitable use ofpublic land; and tax-funded incentives, suchas government procurement, tax rebates, taxfundedsubsidies, and incentive packages.These incentives would have to be supported at<strong>the</strong> same time by appropriate and customisedfinancial, business development, and marketingservices. Mechanisms and financing arrangementsto provide social protection to in<strong>for</strong>malproducers have to be put into place and policyand institutional re<strong>for</strong>m undertaken in a participatorymanner. The participation of in<strong>for</strong>mal entrepreneurs,both women and men, would be bestensured through proactive and iterative dialogue— on an ongoing basis — with representatives ofassociations of in<strong>for</strong>mal entrepreneurs.265


Recommendations and Key MessagesObjectives of Empowerment ProcessLegal empowerment of in<strong>for</strong>mal businessesshould seek to promote an appropriate mix to differenttypes of business rights, and <strong>the</strong> pursuit of<strong>the</strong> following sets of objectives:Broad Objectives• Reducing regulatory burden;• Reducing barriers to <strong>for</strong>mal markets and institutions;• Increasing assets, including property rights;• Expanding market access;• Improving terms of doing business;• Extending legal and social protection;• Increasing organisation and representation.Specific Objectives — Depending on <strong>the</strong>ir sizeand potential <strong>for</strong> growth, in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses needsome combination of <strong>the</strong> following business rights:• Basic business rights: right to w<strong>ork</strong>, includingright to vend; right to a w<strong>ork</strong> space (includingpublic land and private residences), and relatedbasic infrastructure (shelter, electricity, water,sanitation).• Intermediary business rights: right to governmentincentives and support (includingprocurement, tax holidays, export licensing,export promotion); right to public infrastructure(transport and communication).• Advanced business rights: ILD set of legaltools, such as bankruptcy rules, relevant <strong>for</strong>larger, more developed, in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises.Means to Meet ObjectivesDifferent Instruments — Policies and laws, regulationsand procedures, business developmentinfrastructure, and organisation and representationof in<strong>for</strong>mal business.Policy and Regulatory Environment - Legal empowermentof in<strong>for</strong>mal business requires a policyand regulatory environment that:• Provides legal identity to <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor asproducers or traders;• includes representative voice of <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ingpoor in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy;• Recognises and addresses <strong>the</strong> bias in existingcommercial policies, regulations, laws, andprocedures that favour larger firms/enterprises;• Seeks to extend government incentives andprocurements to <strong>the</strong> smallest in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises;• Seeks to build backward and <strong>for</strong>ward linkageson fair terms between larger and smaller firms;• Seeks to promote market access and fair trade<strong>for</strong> smaller firms and enterprises;• Promotes social protection <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal operators(property, health, life, disability insurance)plus retraining, life-long learning, and o<strong>the</strong>rsupport to mobility.The Formalisation Debate:In response to <strong>the</strong> question of whe<strong>the</strong>r and howto <strong>for</strong>malise in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses, <strong>the</strong> Commissionshould highlight <strong>the</strong> point that <strong>for</strong>malisation hasdifferent dimensions:• Expanding <strong>for</strong>mal employment opportunities.• Creating incentives <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises to<strong>for</strong>malise, including1) Simplified registration procedures and progressiveregistration fees;2) Supportive investment climate;3) Fair commercial transactions between in<strong>for</strong>malenterprises and <strong>for</strong>mal firms;4) Appropriate legal and regulatory framew<strong>ork</strong>s,including en<strong>for</strong>ceable commercialcontracts, private property rights, use266


of public space, tax-funded incentives(including government procurement, taxrebates, tax-funded subsidies, and incentivepackages).• Providing financial, business development, andmarketing services to in<strong>for</strong>mal enterprises;• Creating mechanisms and financing arrangementsto provide social protection to in<strong>for</strong>malentrepreneurs;• Promoting participatory policy processes andinclusive rule-setting institutions that includerepresentatives of associations of in<strong>for</strong>malentrepreneurs.267


Chapter 4 Endnotes1 A business has been defined as an organisational entity designedto sell goods and/or services in an ef<strong>for</strong>t to generate profit or a financialreturn. They can be also be a source of employment <strong>for</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs — inaddition to <strong>the</strong> owner and operator - and provide wealth and livelihoodsto <strong>the</strong> owners as well as <strong>the</strong> employees. In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses andIn<strong>for</strong>mal Enterprises are used interchangeably in this report.2 George A. Aryee: ‘Promoting Productivity and Social Protection in<strong>the</strong> Urban In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector - An Integrated Approach. Report on Pilotprojects in Bogota, Dar es Salam and Manila -Summary of activities,lessons and recommendations,’ ILO, 3rd (updated ) edition. Dec 2006ISBN 92-2-110343-9.3 Discussion Paper ‘The In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy,’ Committee onEmployment and Social Policy, ILO, March 2007.4 Woolcock M., ‘Some Initial Thoughts on Empowering In<strong>for</strong>malBusinesses,’ contribution to CLEP, June 2007.5 Hyden G., African Politics in Comparative Perspective,Cambridge University Press, New Y<strong>ork</strong>, 2006.6 Hart, K. (1973) In<strong>for</strong>mal income opportunities and urbanemployment in Ghana. Journal of Modern African Studies, 11, 61-897 Devey, R., Skinner, C,, and Valodia, Imraan. ‘In<strong>for</strong>mal EconomyEmployment Data in South Africa: A Critical Analysis,’ Forum 2003Papers, Development Policy Research Unit, School of Economics,University of Cape Town, http://www.wiego.org/publications/devey%20skinner%20valodia%20In<strong>for</strong>mal%20Economy%20employment%20data%20in%20ZA.pdf8 UNU-WIDER. 2006.9 Stiglitz, J. <strong>Making</strong> Globalization W<strong>ork</strong>. Penguin Group. UK. 2006.p11.10 Stiglitz, J. Op Cit p11. Even if <strong>the</strong> targets of <strong>the</strong> MillenniumDevelopment Goal (MDG) <strong>for</strong> water and sanitation are achieved, <strong>the</strong>rewill still be more than 800 million people without water and 1.8 billionpeople without sanitation in 2015.Summary, Human DevelopmentReport 2006. Beyond Scarcity: Power, poverty and <strong>the</strong> global watercrisis. New Y<strong>ork</strong>. 2006. p13.11 Sen, A. Development as Freedom. 1999. First Anchor Books, USA.12 A business has been defi ned as an organisational entitydesigned to sell goods and/or services in an ef<strong>for</strong>t to generate profi tor a fi nancial return. They can be also be a source of employment <strong>for</strong>o<strong>the</strong>rs — in addition to <strong>the</strong> owner and operator - and provide wealthand livelihoods to <strong>the</strong> owners as well as <strong>the</strong> employees.13 Palmade, V. and Anayiotos, A., Rising In<strong>for</strong>mality, Viewpoint 298,World Bank, Washington D.C., August 200514 Xaba, J. Horn, P. and Motala, S. ‘The In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector in Sub-Saharan Africa’. W<strong>ork</strong>ing paper on <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy, EmploymentSector, International Labour Offi ce, Geneva. 2002. http://www.ilo.org/public/english/employment/infeco/download/ssafrica.pdf, p.315 Charmes, J. (cited at) Women in In<strong>for</strong>mal Employment:Globalisation and Organising (WIEGO), 2 nd Annual Meeting, Cambridge,Massachusetts. 22-24 May 2000.16 ‘Parallel Session III: Integrated Employment and SocialProtection Policies to Upgrade <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy,’ 11th AfricanRegional Meeting, Addis Ababa, 26 April, 2007. http://www.ilo.org/public/english/region/afpro/addisababa/pdf/in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy.pdf, p.117 Mofokeng, C. ‘The In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy in Africa & Its Impacton Women’, Paper presented at <strong>the</strong> Symposium on Women’s Rightsand <strong>the</strong> Role of Women in Africa, Canada, October 3, 2005. http://canadianlabour.ca/updir/africaenwomen.pdf, p.218 ILO DG report ‘The Dilemma of <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector.’ 1991.19 Mofokeng, C. Op Cit. p.6.20 Gallin, D. ‘Organising in <strong>the</strong> Global In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy.’Bogazici University Social Policy Forum: Changing Role of Unions in<strong>the</strong> Contemporary World of Labour, Istanbul, November 26-27, 2004.http://www.global-abour.org/w<strong>ork</strong>ers_in_<strong>the</strong>_in<strong>for</strong>mal_economy.htm21 ‘Market Life in West Africa: Markets and <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy.’http://www.khm.uio.no/utstillinger/madeinafrica/english/marked_6.html22 A market is defi ned as a social arrangement that allows buyersand sellers to discover in<strong>for</strong>mation and carry out a voluntary exchangeof goods or services. It is considered as one of <strong>the</strong> two key institutionsthat organise trade, along with <strong>the</strong> right to own property (Wikipedia).23 Stiglitz, J. Op Cit. Also, nearly 741 million Indians in ruralareas are poorly served, despite a huge demand <strong>for</strong> fi nancial services,including an estimated annual credit demand exceeding $10 billion.24 Sen, A. Op Cit. p.4-5. Opportunities to satisfy hunger, achievesuffi cient nutrition, enjoy clean water and sanitation, receive basiceducation, health care, etc. are among <strong>the</strong> constitutive components ofdevelopment.25 Discovering Hidden Assets. Financing <strong>the</strong> Base of <strong>the</strong> Pyramid.Developing Alternatives. Vol.10, Issue 1. Winter 2005. p4.26 Stiglitz, J. Op Cit.27 Chang, H-J. Stronger than Fiction? Understanding InstitutionalChanges and Economic Development. Policy Brief. UNU-WIDER.Finland. 6 November 2007.28 The underlying assumption of many interventions targetingwomen is that engagement in economic activity will translate intoeconomic empowerment (Safi lios-Rothschild, 1990; Goetz and SenGupta, 1996). Such assumptions rest on <strong>the</strong> belief that women secure<strong>the</strong> benefi ts of <strong>the</strong>ir involvement in an economic activity. However,research has shown that outcomes vary according to both <strong>the</strong> type ofactivity and women’s household circumstances.29 Given a <strong>for</strong>malisation system, an entrepreneur always decideswhe<strong>the</strong>r or not to <strong>for</strong>malise depending on <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong>ir fi rms.Arruñada, B. Pitfalls to Avoid when Measuring Institutions: Is DoingBusiness Damaging Business? Pompeu Fabra University. Barcelona. 17June 2007. p15.30 For instance, according to Friedrich Schneider, citizens behaveaccording to a ‘tax morality’, which describes <strong>the</strong> readiness ofindividuals to leave <strong>the</strong>ir offi cial occupations and enter <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy. If citizens feel that <strong>the</strong>ir government is corrupt, <strong>the</strong>y will feelless inclined to cooperate with state rules and regulations. As such,it is assumed that a declining tax morality increases <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.31 Decent w<strong>ork</strong> and <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. ILO, 90 th Session. 2002.pp.2-332 Recently completed studies of eight countries: Bangladesh,Brazil, Ghana, India, Indonesia, Tunisia, Uganda and Vietnam. Cord,Louise . Promoting Pro-Poor Growth: Lessons from country experiences.The World Bank. In Analysing and Achieving Pro-Poor Growth. Povertyin Focus. International Poverty Centre. UNDP. March 2007.268


33 Chen, M. Rethinking <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy: Linkages with <strong>the</strong>Formal Economy and <strong>the</strong> Formal Regulatory Environment. EGDI andUNU-WIDER Conference ‘Unlocking Human Potential: Linking <strong>the</strong>Formal and In<strong>for</strong>mal Sectors.’ Helsinki, Finland. 17-18 September 200434 Dar es Salaam In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector Survey. 1995. ILO35 Manushi S. <strong>Law</strong>s, Liberty & Livelihood. A bottom up Agenda ofEconomic Re<strong>for</strong>ms. www.manushi-india.org36 Ishengoma, E. K., Kappel, R.. Formalising In<strong>for</strong>mal Firms: Whatcan be done? In Analysing and Achieving Pro-Poor Growth. Poverty inFocus. International Poverty Centre. UNDP. March 200737 Eneste and Schneider, 1998 and WDI, 2002. Includes 53developed and developing countries from all continents exceptAustralia. The OECD country data is based on <strong>the</strong> average WB reportedGDP per capita at constant 1995 US$.38 Loyaza, N. The economics of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector; A simple modeland some empirical evidence from Latin America. World Bank PolicyResearch Papers. 199739 Cord, L. Promoting Pro-Poor Growth: Lessons from countryexperiences. The World Bank. In Analysing and Achieving Pro-PoorGrowth. Poverty in Focus. International Poverty Centre. UNDP. March200740 This section was drawn by and largely from ILO, 2002, Op Cit.41 J. Charmes, cited at Women in In<strong>for</strong>mal Employment: Globalizingand Organising (WIEGO) Second Annual Meeting, Cambridge,Massachusetts, 22-24 May 2000. In ILO, 2002, Op Cit, p.16.42 Op Cit, ILO,p.1643 Carr, M., Chen, M. A.: Globalisation and <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy;How global trade and investment impact on <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor,background paper <strong>for</strong> ILO Report, 2002. May 2001.44 F. Verdera: In<strong>for</strong>mality in Latin America: Recent trends, policiesand prospects. Paper prepared <strong>for</strong> ILO Technical W<strong>ork</strong>shop on Old andNew facets of in<strong>for</strong>mality, Geneva. 2 March 2001.45 http://info.worldbank.org/etools/docs/library/76309/dc2002/proceedings/pdfppt/statistics.pdf46 Nurul Amin, A.T.M. The In<strong>for</strong>mal sector in Asia from <strong>the</strong> decentw<strong>ork</strong> perspective. ILO. 2002.47 The role of in<strong>for</strong>mal sector through <strong>the</strong> stages of developmentand cycles of economic growth: The Asia Evidence. Paper presentedat <strong>the</strong> ILO Technical W<strong>ork</strong>shop on Old and New Facets of In<strong>for</strong>mality.Geneva. 2 March 2001.48 WIEGO-Women in In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy: Globalising and Organising,www.wiego.org49 Lundström, S. and Ronnås, P., Swedish InternationalDevelopment Cooperation Agency, Sida in Analysing and achieving Pro-Poor Growth. International Poverty Centre, March 2007. Brazil.50 Sangathan, M., Op Cit.51 Ishengoma, E. K., Kappel, R. Formalising In<strong>for</strong>mal Firms: Whatcan be done? March 2007. Op Cit.52 Legal Identity <strong>for</strong> Inclusive Development. ADB. 2007. ThePhilippines. p.xiv-xv53 While it is estimated that <strong>the</strong> achievement of water andsanitation related MDG Goals require an additional annual funding ofUS$10-US$25billion, <strong>the</strong> scenario would appear distinctively differentand be more manageable if <strong>the</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>ts to achieve <strong>the</strong>se targets aresupplemented by service delivery through PPPs particularly through <strong>the</strong>empowerment of <strong>the</strong> local communities to manage <strong>the</strong>ir need througheffective value chain strategies. The same rationale will apply <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>provision of an estimated US$700 billion of investment required tobring electricity to an additional US$1.4billion people.54 Rodrik, Dani. The Limits of Self En<strong>for</strong>cing Contracts. ReactionEssay. August 9, 2007.55 The world’s fastest growing market now, it argues, is at <strong>the</strong>‘bottom of <strong>the</strong> pyramid.’ With nearly four billion people living onless than US$1500/year, <strong>the</strong> opportunities <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> private sector aresizeable.56 Bannock, G. et al. (2002) Indigenous Private Sector Developmentand Regulation in Africa and Central Europe: A 10 Country Study.London: Bannock Consulting.57 World Bank, Doing Business Report 2003-200658 World Bank, Doing Business Report, 2007.59 USAID, Removing Barriers to Formalisation: The Case <strong>for</strong> Re<strong>for</strong>mand Emerging Best Practice, 200560 De Soto, H. 1989. The O<strong>the</strong>r Path (New Y<strong>ork</strong>: Basic Books)61 Ibid.62 Ibid.63 Building Resources Across Communities (<strong>for</strong>merly known asBangladesh Rural Advancement Committee)64 ILD paper on Legal Tools to Empower In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses,submitted in 2006 to our w<strong>ork</strong>ing group on Chapter 4.65 De Soto, Hernando. 1989. The O<strong>the</strong>r Path (New Y<strong>ork</strong>: BasicBooks), and 2000. The Mystery of Capital (New Y<strong>ork</strong>: Basic Books).66 ILO DGReport ‘The Dilemma of <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector’ 199167 Woolcock M., ‘ Some Initial Thoughts on Empowering In<strong>for</strong>malBusinesses,’ a note to CLEP W<strong>ork</strong>ing Group 4, June 2006.68 UN Report on Social Development 2005.69 State of <strong>the</strong> World 2007: Our Urban Future, Worldwatch Institute.70 An estimated 1.6 million urban residents die each year due tolack of clean water and sanitation as a result. Cities Key to TacklingPoverty, Climate Change, Worldwatch Institute, January 10, 2007.71 Sheehan, M. State of <strong>the</strong> World 2007 Project Director.‘Policymakers need to address <strong>the</strong> ‘urbanization of poverty’ by steppingup investments in education, healthcare, and infrastructure.’ From1970 to 2000, urban aid worldwide was estimated at US$60 billion —just 4 percent of <strong>the</strong> US$1.5 trillion in total development assistance.72 A study sponsored by <strong>the</strong> World Bank in Luanda involved ananalysis of <strong>the</strong> existing in<strong>for</strong>mal water market and <strong>the</strong> communities’willingness to pay <strong>for</strong> services or participate in <strong>the</strong> programme in o<strong>the</strong>rways. More than 50 percent of Luanda’s population, and most who live in<strong>the</strong> musseques, do not have access to piped water. The peri-urban andmusseque population is <strong>for</strong>ced to pay extremely high prices <strong>for</strong> (oftenuntreated) water pumped from <strong>the</strong> Bengo River and distributed by tankertrucks to in<strong>for</strong>mal sellers in <strong>the</strong> various bairros. While <strong>the</strong> private sectorhas stepped in to provide an essential service that <strong>the</strong> state has failedto deliver, <strong>the</strong> costs are very high, because of <strong>the</strong> extreme inefficiency ofdelivering water to <strong>the</strong> bairros by tanker truck ra<strong>the</strong>r than by pipe. Thestudy of <strong>the</strong> water market demonstrated that musseque residents wereaccustomed to paying up to 10,000 times more <strong>for</strong> water to <strong>the</strong> privatesellers than <strong>the</strong> well-to-do in <strong>the</strong> cement city were paying <strong>for</strong> treatedwater piped to <strong>the</strong>ir household taps by <strong>the</strong> provincial water company.Ironically <strong>the</strong> poor were far more accustomed to pay dearly <strong>for</strong> services269


than <strong>the</strong> rich. It fur<strong>the</strong>r demonstrated that US$35 million per year waspaid by <strong>the</strong> urban poor <strong>for</strong> purchasing water, and that much of thisincome could eventually be recovered in water fees if a just set of tariffswas set at equitable prices <strong>for</strong> all consumers. Cain, A. Livelihoods and <strong>the</strong>In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy in Post-War Angola. Published in Monograph No. 102,August 2004. Supporting Sustainable Livelihoods-A Critical Review ofAssistance in Post-conflict Situations. Edited by Clover, J. and Cornwell, R.73 Sachs, J. Capacity-net. E-DISCUSSION: Capacity to effectivelyand sustainably deliver local basic services to <strong>the</strong> poor. Consider acountry at US$300 per capita. It typically raises around 15 percent ofGNP in tax revenues, or US$45 per capita <strong>for</strong> all government services.If it is very well governed, it perhaps devotes 20 percent of <strong>the</strong> budgetto health, or US$9 per capita per year.74 ILO: A Global Agenda <strong>for</strong> Employment: Discussion Paper.75 Besley, T., Burgess, R. and Esteve-Volart, B. The Policy Originsof Poverty and Growth in India. In Analysing and Achieving Pro-PoorGrowth. March 2007. International Poverty Centre. UNDP76 Decent w<strong>ork</strong> and <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. ILO. 2002. p3577 Over <strong>the</strong> last nearly three decades, micro-fi nance has servednearly 100 million people in nearly 100 countries.78 For example, commercial banks in Latin America were knownto enter <strong>the</strong> micro-fi nance markets after a decline in <strong>the</strong> reserverequirements imposed on <strong>the</strong>m from 50percent to about 10-30percentwas introduced.79 ILO. 1999. Central bank of <strong>the</strong> West African States: Data Bank onmicro-fi nance institutions in West African Monetary Union.80 While targeted savings and consumption loans includingRotating Savings and Credit Societies and savings clubs can help<strong>the</strong> poor to cope with day-to-day events, but as risks increase inmagnitude and uncertainty, <strong>the</strong> losses increase and simple savingsand loan activities are unable to manage those losses. Brown, W. WhyMFIs are providing insurance to low income people? 2000. Dhaka81 Kawas, C. and Gitterman, M. 2000. Roundtable on MicroinsuranceServices in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy: The Role of Micro-fi nanceInstitutions. The Ford Foundation. New Y<strong>ork</strong>.82 Cohen, Monique and Jennefer Sebstad. 2003. ReducingVulnerability: The Demand <strong>for</strong> Microinsurance. Microsave-Africa. Nairobi.83 The remittance transfer market is limited; it is dominated by <strong>the</strong>Western Union with Visa and Mastercard having a signifi cant share.84 For instance, currently US$100 remitted to Venezuela translatesinto only US$50 received by <strong>the</strong> receiver.85 World Bank Assistance to Agriculture in Sub-Saharan Africa:An IEG Review. Independent Evaluation Group. The World Bank.Washington DC. 200786 Stiglitz, J. Op Cit. Also, nearly 741 million Indians in ruralareas are poorly served, despite a huge demand <strong>for</strong> fi nancial services,including an estimated annual credit demand exceeding US$10 billion87 Not surprisingly, various reports have been advising <strong>the</strong> UNto streng<strong>the</strong>n its relationship with <strong>the</strong> private sector The MonterreyConsensus highlights <strong>the</strong> necessity to engage <strong>the</strong> private sectoras a prerequisite <strong>for</strong> poverty alleviation. The report of <strong>the</strong> UN’sCommission on <strong>the</strong> Private Sector and Development entitled ‘UnleashingEntrepreneurship — <strong>Making</strong> Business W<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor’ emphasisesimproving <strong>the</strong> environment <strong>for</strong> private sector development and privateinvestment. The UN Millennium Project Report urges <strong>the</strong> private sectorto play a central role in reducing income poverty through inclusive andsustainable economic growth, while encouraging governments to provide<strong>the</strong> enabling environment <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>m to do so. In highlighting <strong>the</strong> need<strong>for</strong> new partnerships to tackle global challenges and achieve globallyagreed priorities, Report of <strong>the</strong> Panel of Eminent Persons on UnitedNations-Civil Society relations, underscores <strong>the</strong> need to connect <strong>the</strong> localwith <strong>the</strong> Global and <strong>the</strong> critical role of non state actors including <strong>the</strong>private sector as partners in policy-making and decision-making.88 The world’s fastest growing market now, it argues, is at <strong>the</strong>‘bottom of <strong>the</strong> pyramid.’ With nearly four billion people living on lessthan US$1500/year, <strong>the</strong> opportunities <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> private sector are sizeable.89 Chang, H.-J. Stronger than Fiction? Understanding InstitutionalChanges and Economic Development. Policy Brief. UNU-WIDER.Finland. 6 November 2007.90 The underlying assumption of many interventions targetingwomen is that engagement in economic activity will translate intoeconomic empowerment (Safi lios-Rothschild, 1990; Goetz and SenGupta, 1996). Such assumptions rest on <strong>the</strong> belief that women secure<strong>the</strong> benefi ts of <strong>the</strong>ir involvement in an economic activity. However,research has shown that outcomes vary according to both <strong>the</strong> type ofactivity and women’s household circumstances.91 Dickerson, C. OHADA countries in Western and Central Africa.92 ILD ‘Best Practices to Empower Business Organisation —Gabriel Daly,’ December 2006.93 Benchmarking <strong>the</strong> Administration of Business Start-ups, FinalReport; prepared by CSES <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Enterprise Directorate General of <strong>the</strong>European Commission; 200294 Hyden G., African Politics in Comparative Perspective,Cambridge University Press, New Y<strong>ork</strong>, 2006.95 Makerere University Business School, Global EntrepreneurshipMonitor: GEM Uganda 2004 Executive Report, <strong>the</strong> GEM website, 2007.96 Bannock G. and Kapila S., from notes <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> draft SessionalPaper on MSEs in Kenya, 2004.97 Hyden G., African Politics.98 Ibid.99 Benito Arruñada ‘Pitfalls to Avoid when Measuring Institutions:Is Doing Business Damaging Business?’ Dept. of Economics andBusiness. Universitat Pompeu Fabra. Trias Fargas, 25. 08005-Barcelona (Spain) June 17, 2007.100 Ibid.101 Scott, J. (1998) Seeing Like a State: How Well-IntentionedSchemes to Improve <strong>the</strong> Human Condition Have Failed New Haven: YaleUniversity PressPritchett, L. and Woolcock, M. (2004) ‘Solutions when <strong>the</strong> Solution is<strong>the</strong> Problem: Arraying <strong>the</strong> Disarray in Development’ World Development32(2): 191-212.102 Ibid.103 Woolcock, M. (2007) ‘ Notes to <strong>the</strong> Commission’s In<strong>for</strong>malBusinesses W<strong>ork</strong>ing Group: World Bank.104 Sobhan, R. ‘A Macro Policy <strong>for</strong> Poverty Eradication throughStructural Change.’ UN University, Wider, January 2005.105 This section was contributed by Prof. Rehman Sobhan, op. cit.106 Ibid.107 USAID, 2006270


Chapter 4 BibliographyADB, ‘Legal Identity <strong>for</strong> Inclusive Development’. 2007. Manila,Philippines.Amin, A.T.M. Nurul. ‘The In<strong>for</strong>mal sector in Asia from <strong>the</strong> decent w<strong>ork</strong>perspective’. ILO. 2002.Arruñada, Benito. ‘Pitfalls to Avoid When Measuring Institutions: IsDoing Business Damaging Business?’ Pompeu FabraUniversity. Barcelona. June 2007.Aryee, George A.: ‘Promoting Productivity and Social Protection in <strong>the</strong>Urban In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector — An Integrated Approach. Reporton Pilot projects in Bogota, Dar es Salam and Manila -Summary of activities,lessons and recommendations’ ILO,third (updated ) edition Dec 2006Bannock, G. et al. ‘Indigenous Private Sector Development andRegulation in Africa and Central Europe: A 10 CountryStudy.’ London, Bannock Consulting. 2002Besley, Timothy, Robert Burgess and Berta Esteve-Volart. The PolicyOrigins of Poverty and Growth in India. In Analysing andAchieving Pro-Poor Growth. March 2007. InternationalPoverty Centre. UNDPBrown, Warren. ‘Why MFIs are providing insurance to low incomepeople?’ Dhaka, 2000. Cain, Allan. ‘Livelihoods and <strong>the</strong>In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy in Post-War Angola’. Published inMonograph No. 102, August 2004.Brustinow, Angelika, ‘<strong>Making</strong> Rights W<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor; AlternativeDispute Resolution.’ Prepared by, UNECE, 2006.CARE, Canada, ‘Heads or Tails — Extra National Dimensions ofInternational Development’ April 2007.______., ‘The Missing Middle of Investment in Developing Countries’Aril 2007______., ‘The Story of John and Juan- Social Entrepreneurialism andbarriers to <strong>the</strong> business <strong>for</strong>mation’ February 2007Carr, M., M. A. Chen: Globalization and <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy; Howglobal trade and investment impact on <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing poor,background paper <strong>for</strong> ILO Report, 2002. May 2001Chang, Ha-Joon. ‘Understanding Institutional Changes and EconomicDevelopment’ Policy Brief. UNU-WIDER. Finland. 6November 2007.Charmes, Jacques, (cited in) Women in In<strong>for</strong>mal Employment:Globalization and Organising (WIEGO), 2 nd Annual Meeting,Cambridge, Massachusetts. 22-24 May 2000.Chen, Martha ‘Empowerment of In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses: Legal and o<strong>the</strong>rInterventions’ Harvard University, Coordinator WIEGO Dec2006______ , ‘Legal Mechanisms to Empower In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses:Unpacking <strong>the</strong> Issue,’ Harvard University , Coordinator,WIEGO Dec 2006______., ‘Institutional Mismatch — Formal Institutions and In<strong>for</strong>malRealities, May 2007.______., ‘In<strong>for</strong>malisation of Labour Markets: Is Formalisation <strong>the</strong>Answer?’ Harvard University, Coordinator WIEGO.______., ‘Mapping size and diversity of in<strong>for</strong>mal economy’ May 2007.______., ‘The Business Environment and <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy —creating conditions <strong>for</strong> Poverty reduction’ November 2005.______.. Rethinking <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy: Linkages with <strong>the</strong> FormalEconomy and <strong>the</strong> Formal Regulatory Environment. EGDIand UNU-WIDER Conference ‘Unlocking Human Potential:Linking <strong>the</strong> Formal and In<strong>for</strong>mal Sectors.’ Helsinki, Finland.Sept. 2004Cohen, Monique and Jennefer Sebstad. Reducing Vulnerability: TheDemand <strong>for</strong> Microinsurance. Microsave-Africa. Nairobi.Consultative Group <strong>for</strong> Poor (CGAP), World Bank, ‘Safe and Accessible:Bringing poor saver into <strong>for</strong>mal fi nancial system’September 2006.Cord, Louise. Promoting Pro-Poor Growth: Lessons from countryexperiences. The World Bank. In Analysing and AchievingPro-Poor Growth. Poverty in Focus. International PovertyCentre. UNDP. March 2007Crecentia, Mofokeng. ‘The In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy in Africa & Its Impact onWomen,’ Paper presented at <strong>the</strong> Symposium on Women’sRights and <strong>the</strong> Role of Women in Africa, Canada, October3, 2005Dayaratna-Banda, O. G., ‘In<strong>for</strong>mal Trade in Sri Lanka,’ Departmentof Economics and Statistics, Faculty of Arts, University ofPeradeniya, Peradeniya, 20400, Sri Lanka, Nov.2006.De Soto, Hernando. The O<strong>the</strong>r Path (New Y<strong>ork</strong>: Basic Books), 1989 and .The Mystery of Capital (New Y<strong>ork</strong>: Basic Books) 2000.Devey, Richard, Skinner, Caroline, and Valodia, Imraan. ‘In<strong>for</strong>malEconomy Employment Data in South Africa: A CriticalAnalysis,’ Forum Papers, Development Policy Research Unit,School of Economics, University of Cape Town, 2003Discovering Hidden Assets-Financing <strong>the</strong> Base of <strong>the</strong> Pyramid.Developing Alternatives. Vol.10, Issue 1. Winter 2005.Djankov, Simeon, Ira Lieberman, Joyita Mukherjee, and Tatiana Nenova,‘Going In<strong>for</strong>mal: Benefi ts and Costs,’ World Bank, 2002FIAS/World Bank Group-ISSER, ‘Regional Conference on EnterpriseFormalisation in Africa,’ Accra, Ghana, January 10-11,2007Gallin, Dan. ‘Organising in <strong>the</strong> Global In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy’, BogaziciUniversity Social Policy Forum: Changing Role of Unionsin <strong>the</strong> Contemporary World of Labor, Istanbul, November26-27, 2004.Golub, Stephen, ‘Beyond Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Orthodoxy — The LegalEmpowerment Alternative,’ Carnegie Endowment, October2003.Government of India ‘Report on Social Security <strong>for</strong> UnorganisedW<strong>ork</strong>ers,’ prepared by <strong>the</strong> National Commission <strong>for</strong>Enterprises in <strong>the</strong> Unorganised Sector, Government of India.May 2006.Hart, K. In<strong>for</strong>mal income opportunities and urban employment inGhana. Journal of Modern African Studies, 1973.Hyden G., African Politics in Comparative Perspective, CambridgeUniversity Press, New Y<strong>ork</strong>, 2006.ILO, DG report ‘The Dilemma of <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector’ 1991______., Dar es Salaam In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector Survey. 1995.______. Central bank of <strong>the</strong> West African States: Data Bank on microfinance institutions in West African Monetary Union, 1999______., Decent w<strong>ork</strong> and <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. , 90 th Session. 2002271


______., ‘Ghana Decent W<strong>ork</strong> Pilot Programme- Ghana W<strong>ork</strong>ing Out ofPoverty’, January 2006.______., Discussion Paper ‘The In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy’, Committee onEmployment and Social Policy, March 2007______.: A Global Agenda <strong>for</strong> Employment: Discussion PaperILO, UNIDO, UNDP ‘Roadmap Study of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector in mainlandTanzania’, 2002.Indon, Reginald ‘Legal Mechanisms to Empower In<strong>for</strong>mal Businesses-Philippines Experience,’ February 2007Ishengoma, Es<strong>the</strong>r K and Robert Kappel, ‘Economic Growth andPoverty: Does Formalisation of In<strong>for</strong>mal Enterprises Matter,’German institute of Global and Area Studies, April 2006______., Formalising In<strong>for</strong>mal Firms: What can be done? In Analysingand Achieving Pro-Poor Growth. Poverty in Focus.International Poverty Centre. UNDP. March 2007Kapila, Sunita, ‘Unleashing <strong>the</strong> Entrepreneurial Potential of Microand Small Businesses in Kenya: Some Experiences andDirections,’ Nairobi, October 2006.Karunagoda, Nanda, ‘In<strong>for</strong>mal Markets <strong>for</strong> Financial Services in SriLanka,’ Sri Lanka, Aug.2006Kashyap, Arun, ‘Business Rights - Outline and Framew<strong>ork</strong>,’ UNDP, July-October 2007.Kawas, Celina and Marla Gitterman. Roundtable on MicroinsuranceServices in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy: The Role of Micro-fi nanceInstitutions .The Ford Foundation. New Y<strong>ork</strong>. 2000Kenyon, Thomas and Emerson Kapaz, ‘In<strong>for</strong>mality Trap’ Public Policy <strong>for</strong>Private Sector, World Bank, Dec 2005.Kuchta-Helbling, Ca<strong>the</strong>rine ‘Background Paper — Barriers toparticipation: The in<strong>for</strong>mal sector in emerging democracies’The World Movement <strong>for</strong> Democracy, Sao Paulo, Brazil, 2000Lex Mundi Pro Bono Foundation ‘Technical Papers from Bangladesh,Thailand, Philippines, Mexico, Bolivia, Peru, South Africa,Sri Lanka’Loyaza, Norman. The economics of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal sector; A simple modeland some empirical evidence from Latin America. WorldBank Policy Research Papers. 1997Loayza, N. and Jamele Rigolini,’ In<strong>for</strong>mality Trends and Cycles’ TheWorld Bank, 2005Lundström, Susanna and Per Ronnås, Swedish InternationalDevelopment Cooperation Agency, Sida in ‘Analysing andachieving Pro-Poor Growth.’ International Poverty Centre,Brazil, March 2007.Moore Dickerson, Claire, ‘Harmonizing Business <strong>Law</strong>s in Africa’ OHADA,2005______., ‘Legal Mechanisms to empower in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses— suggested outline and notes’ June 2007.Musiolek Bettina, W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper on In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy ‘Decent W<strong>ork</strong>in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector: Central and Eastern Europe / andCommon Wealth of Independent States and o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>merSoviet Republics,’ ILO. 2002.Nicholas, Stephen and Elizabeth Maitland, ‘How business interactswith in<strong>for</strong>mal institutions,’ OECD, 2005Ocici, Charles, ‘Entrepreneurship- Ugandan Experience’, International<strong>Law</strong> Institute, Ugandan, African Centre <strong>for</strong> LegalExcellence, Kampala Uganda, November 2006.Olomi,. Donath R.,’Unleashing Entrepreneurial Potentials of <strong>the</strong> Poorin Tanzania: Prospects, Challenges and Way Forward.’University of Dar es Salaam Entrepreneurship Centre(UDEC), Dar-e- Salaam, Tanzania, November 2006.Palmade, Vincent and Andrea Anayiotos, Rising In<strong>for</strong>mality, Viewpoint298, World Bank, Washington D.C., August 2005Pasquel, Enrique, ‘Legal Tools to Empower Business Organisations- A New Approach to Formalisation’ prepared by ILD, Lima,Peru, December, 2006Daly, Gabriel ‘Best Practices to Empower Business Organisationsprepared by, ILD, Lima, Peru, Dec 2006.Khoudeir, Ayman H. R.: The In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector Impacts on <strong>the</strong>Environment- In Reference to Egypt prepared by of SocialFund, Cairo, Egypt. Dec 2006Pritchett, Lant and Michael Woolcock, ‘Solutions when <strong>the</strong> Solution is<strong>the</strong> Problem: Arraying <strong>the</strong> Disarray in Development’ WorldDevelopment 32(2): 2004Sangathan, Manushi. <strong>Law</strong>s, Liberty & Livelihood. A bottom up Agendaof Economic Re<strong>for</strong>ms. www.manushi-india.orgSarvananthan, Muttukrishna’In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy in <strong>the</strong> Confl ict AffectedRegion of Sri Lanka: An Exploration, The Pathfi nderFoundation, Colombo, Sri Lanka. August 2006.Scott, James ‘Seeing Like a State: How Well-Intentioned Schemes toImprove <strong>the</strong> Human Condition Have Failed ‘ New Haven:Yale University Press1998.Sen, Amartya. ‘Development as Freedom’. First Anchor Books, USA.1999SEWA ‘ Public Private Partnership in Agriculture — SEWA’s experienceand Recommendations, SEWA, Ahmedabad, India.November 2006.SEWA, ‘Self-employed Women’s Association Trade Facilitation Centre(SFTC) — An Overview,’ Prepared by SEWA, Ahmedabad,India.Sobhan, Rehman ‘A Macro Policy <strong>for</strong> Poverty Eradication throughStructural Change,’ UN University, Wider, January 2005State of <strong>the</strong> World: ‘Our Urban Future,’ Worldwatch Institute. 2007Stiglitz, Joseph. ‘Beyond Scarcity: Power. Poverty and <strong>the</strong> global watercrisis.’ New Y<strong>ork</strong>. 2006.______.. ‘<strong>Making</strong> Globalization W<strong>ork</strong>’. Penguin Group. UK. 2006.UN Report on Social Development 2005UNDP, ‘Growing Inclusive Markets: Business W<strong>ork</strong>s fro Development,Development w<strong>ork</strong>s <strong>for</strong> Business,’ June 2007UNDP, ‘Unleashing Entrepreneurship, <strong>Making</strong> Business W<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>Poor,’ March 2004.United Nations Expert Group on Women and Finance, Women’s WorldBanking, 1994USAID, Removing Barriers to Formalisation: The Case <strong>for</strong> Re<strong>for</strong>m andEmerging Best Practice, 2005______. ‘Land and Business Formalisation <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor’ Nov, 2006.Verdera, F. In<strong>for</strong>mality in Latin America: Recent trends, policies andprospects. Paper prepared <strong>for</strong> ILO Technical W<strong>ork</strong>shop onOld and New facets of in<strong>for</strong>mality, Geneva. March 2001.272


WIEGO, ‘Accra Hawkers Association,’ News from Ghana Daily Graphic,May 2006,WIEGO Women in In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy: Globalising and Organising, www.wiego.orgWomen’s World Banking, ‘Banking <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Majority: Profi table andResponsible Micro Finance,’ Federation of Latin AmericanBanks and Women’s World Banking. 1994.Women’s World Banking, Client Case Studies from <strong>the</strong> DominicanRepublic, Bank ADOPEM, Women’s World Banking, NewY<strong>ork</strong>, USA, www.swwb.orgWoolcock M., ‘Some Initial Thoughts on Empowering In<strong>for</strong>malBusinesses,’ World Bank notes to CLEP, June 2007.World Bank ‘Doing Business 2007 — How to Re<strong>for</strong>m’, September 2006.______. ‘Rural Investment Climate Survey: Indonesia,’ September2006.______., Doing Business Report 2003-2006Xaba, Jantjie, Horn, Pat, and Motala, Shirin. ‘The In<strong>for</strong>mal Sectorin Sub-Saharan Africa.’ W<strong>ork</strong>ing paper on <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy, Employment Sector, International Labour Offi ce,Geneva. 2002.273


ChapterFIVERoad Maps <strong>for</strong>Implementationof Re<strong>for</strong>msImplementation Strategies,Including Toolkits and Indices275


EXECUTIVE SUMMARYExisting power structures prevent poor people from taking charge of <strong>the</strong>ir lives and occupations andachieving upward mobility. To end poverty, those structures must be reorganised — a challenging task dueto <strong>the</strong> many dimensions of poverty and disempowerment. Interchangeable solutions do not w<strong>ork</strong> acrosscountries in exactly <strong>the</strong> same ways; practitioners must be inventive and experimental to produce more justrelationships among <strong>the</strong> state, <strong>the</strong> marketplace and <strong>the</strong> poor.Listening to <strong>the</strong> poor and learning by doingare critically important. Civil societies,non-governmental organisations, membership-basedgroups of employers and of w<strong>ork</strong>ers,coalitions and netw<strong>ork</strong>s have major roles to play ingenerating and articulating bottom-up demand <strong>for</strong>legal empowerment. Support of central authoritiesis also vital <strong>for</strong> sustaining progress in most countries.Policy champions are needed to bring o<strong>the</strong>rgovernment actors on board to preclude policyspoilers from blocking implementation of legalempowerment.Implementation of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor(Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor) in a countrybegins with contextual analysis, focusing on <strong>the</strong>social and cultural features that could affectimplementation. Consideration must also be givento <strong>the</strong> economic context (which can be both a helpand a hindrance), and to <strong>the</strong> openness and capacityof <strong>the</strong> state. Supplementing <strong>the</strong> inventory of<strong>the</strong>se concerns should be a careful analysis of <strong>the</strong>reach and hold that in<strong>for</strong>mal institutions have on<strong>the</strong> poor. A full contextual analysis <strong>for</strong>ms <strong>the</strong> basis<strong>for</strong> a feasibility review of various empowermentscenarios.The most important constraints set by <strong>the</strong> nationalsocio-political context are:• The domestic social structure, especially its gender,class and ethnic makeup, as well as culturalattitudes toward participation and equality;• The economic context — including <strong>the</strong> distributionof wealth and income, and <strong>the</strong> level and rateof economic growth;• The characteristics of <strong>the</strong> state — both <strong>the</strong> politicaland <strong>the</strong> administrative system;• The extent of economic and political in<strong>for</strong>malityand tensions with <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal and officially recognisedsystems.Practitioners and policymakers can use <strong>the</strong> tool ofcontextual analysis within a country to determine:1) if conditions appear ripe <strong>for</strong> legal empowermentre<strong>for</strong>ms; 2) which implementation options seemmost probable; 3) what sequencing and timelines<strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m look doable; 4) how <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms shouldbe designed; 5) what tradeoffs need to be considered;6) which risk-mitigating mechanisms areworth trying, and 7) what contextual variables needcareful monitoring during implementation.276


Following <strong>the</strong> contextual analysis — or perhapssimultaneously with it since implementation stepsare never discrete — local activists and externalchange agents should undertake a stakeholderanalysis of <strong>the</strong> constituencies concerned with LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. The objective is to differentiateamong <strong>the</strong> superficially homogeneousbeneficiaries, to better understand <strong>the</strong> divisions,alliances and particular needs that exist among<strong>the</strong> poor. O<strong>the</strong>r stakeholders who might opposeor assist <strong>the</strong> target group or groups also need tobe scrutinised to see what motivates <strong>the</strong>ir behaviourand to reflect on how <strong>the</strong>y could be broughtinto <strong>the</strong> process. The purpose of <strong>the</strong> stakeholderanalysis is to get a firmer grasp of <strong>the</strong> probabilityof moving <strong>for</strong>ward with various legal empowermentalternatives, and to begin serious thinking aboutwhat it might take to build a minimum winningcoalition <strong>for</strong> legal empowerment in <strong>the</strong> country.Stakeholders act out of regard <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir own advantage,as <strong>the</strong>y define it. Poor people are <strong>the</strong> targetbeneficiaries of legal empowerment and need tohave as big a hand as possible in initiating anddesigning <strong>the</strong> relevant policies. Even though <strong>the</strong>ylack physical, financial or organisational resources,and even social capital in many locales, <strong>the</strong> pooralways have a passive capacity to derail legalre<strong>for</strong>ms aimed at <strong>the</strong>m. Because poor stakeholdersare diverse, legal empowerment policies may havesurprisingly uneven impact if officials are inattentiveto <strong>the</strong> needs and preferences of <strong>the</strong> intendedbeneficiaries.Legal empowerment also creates policy ‘losers’,no matter what <strong>the</strong> broader merits are. It oftenredistributes a right or benefit from one group ofstakeholders to ano<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>for</strong> example when <strong>the</strong>reare mutually exclusive claims to a fixed resourcesuch as fertile land or minerals. Policymakers mayendeavour to minimise redistributive conflicts byexpanding economic opportunities so that differentinterests can be negotiated to meet every side’sneeds, but plenty of potential <strong>for</strong> confrontationremains because important stakeholders believeo<strong>the</strong>rs’ gains come at <strong>the</strong>ir expense. The mutualpayoff to legal empowerment is in <strong>the</strong> future, but<strong>the</strong> individual sacrifices must be borne now.Finally (though again <strong>the</strong> chronology wouldprobably be overlapping), <strong>the</strong> internal technicalfeatures of <strong>the</strong> alternative courses of action mustbe reviewed. Policy characteristics analysis wouldfocus on <strong>the</strong> complexities of <strong>the</strong> different policies,<strong>the</strong>ir ambiguity, and <strong>the</strong>ir potential to sow discord— all of which may hinder implementation. Ef<strong>for</strong>tswould be made to find a simple, incremental, andsustainable way <strong>for</strong>ward, and to avoid as muchas possible taking steps that provoke needlessconfrontation.Obviously, what legally empowers <strong>the</strong> poor in onenation may be unsuitable in ano<strong>the</strong>r country, where<strong>the</strong>re would likely be a different social structure,economic environment and universe of stakeholdergroups. The procedures in determining a suitablere<strong>for</strong>m strategy might look alike in both countries,but <strong>the</strong> substance of <strong>the</strong> outcome would be sharplydifferent. And in all cases, <strong>the</strong> process is messyand imprecise, yielding only what appear to be <strong>the</strong>best fitting policies, given <strong>the</strong> imperfect in<strong>for</strong>mationavailable to policymakers at <strong>the</strong> time andunder <strong>the</strong> political realities.Development professionals must creatively seekto capitalise on <strong>the</strong> specific situation at hand,placing front and centre poor people’s perceptions.While legal or organisational re<strong>for</strong>ms may appearself-evidently empowering to outside experts, <strong>the</strong>yshould be cautioned that a poor community mightsee <strong>the</strong>m as dangerous from <strong>the</strong>ir own perspective.It may be best to move <strong>for</strong>ward selectively and notdissipate energy on too many legal or regulatoryinitiatives at once. Empowerment policies seldom277


take effect quickly. Individual uncertainty aboutimplementation encourages poor people to withholdsupport <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms, which can create self-fulfillingprophecies of slippage. One should <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>elook <strong>for</strong> interventions promising short-term rewards<strong>for</strong> beneficiaries. Design simplicity should be a keyconsideration to minimise conflict, uncertainty, ando<strong>the</strong>r implementation problems arising from <strong>the</strong>procedural and technical traits of legal empowermentactivities.Roadmaps to ImplementationEffective implementation of policy re<strong>for</strong>m takesa mix of experience, professional judgment, andwillingness to take chances. Creative policymakerslook to open up policy windows that create <strong>the</strong>space needed to move <strong>for</strong>ward in solving particularproblems even under difficult circumstances.Six common sets of tasks are associated withdeveloping specific national roadmaps <strong>for</strong> LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. They follow a generalized(but not lockstep) pattern, conceived as aninteractive cycle launched by a stream of issues,agendas and decisions that, over time, provide additionalinput and momentum to <strong>the</strong> process.• Issues, Agendas, and Decisions: Advocate <strong>for</strong>change, develop policy issues, and make decisionsto launch policy re<strong>for</strong>ms. Although politiciansand interest groups tend to take <strong>the</strong> lead,<strong>the</strong>y will seldom succeed without pressure frombelow, and mobilisation from among <strong>the</strong> poor<strong>the</strong>mselves, including <strong>the</strong>ir demands.• Policy Formulation and Legitimisation: Address<strong>the</strong> technical content of re<strong>for</strong>m measures. However,besides technical content, re<strong>for</strong>m measuresneed to be accepted and be seen as necessaryand important. Through <strong>the</strong>ir representatives, <strong>the</strong>poor should be part of <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m design process.• Constituency Building: Convince beneficiaries of<strong>the</strong> advantages of re<strong>for</strong>ms, and demonstrate thatlong-term benefits are worth short-term costs.• Resource Mobilisation: Ensure <strong>the</strong> flow of adequateresources by addressing incentives, andexercising leadership in galvanizing constituencies.Financial, technical, and human resourcecommitments are needed.• Implementation Design and Organisational Development:Re<strong>for</strong>mers need to create and nurturenetw<strong>ork</strong>s and partnerships <strong>for</strong> cooperation andcoordination, and provide <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> developmentof new organisational skills and capacities in <strong>the</strong>public, private and non-governmental sectors.Old procedures, operating routines, and communicationpatterns are difficult to root out; changeis likely to be resisted within some quarters.• Action Planning and Progress Monitoring: Set upsystems and procedures <strong>for</strong> obtaining feedbackso that implementation is related to learning andadaptation, so as to produce results and impact.Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor may be perceivedas a spectrum that provides opportunities, protectionand security to beneficiaries. It establishes aminimum ‘floor’ of entitlements and safeguardsto which everyone is entitled, by <strong>the</strong> simple factof our common humanity. The task is to establishthis floor using human rights law. For every facetof empowerment, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, one test is to identifya range of potential policy options from which nationsand citizens can choose, depending on <strong>the</strong>irnational context and <strong>the</strong> different starting points ofvarious groups of <strong>the</strong> poor within <strong>the</strong>m. Finally, aspectrum approach explicitly recognises <strong>the</strong> incrementalmanner in which poor people improve <strong>the</strong>irlives in practice.Implementation of empowering policies at <strong>the</strong>national level should seek to integrate legalempowerment into existing processes, such as<strong>the</strong> preparation of national development plans orpoverty reduction strategies, ra<strong>the</strong>r than seek to278


establish a ‘legal empowerment programme’ as astand-alone entity. Ano<strong>the</strong>r important dimension ofnational level w<strong>ork</strong> will involve w<strong>ork</strong>ing closely withprofessional associations to create a new cadre oflegal, engineering or o<strong>the</strong>r para-professionals toassist poor men and women.The base organisation of <strong>the</strong> poor must be engagedin <strong>the</strong> design of interventions of any kind. In<strong>for</strong>mationdissemination will be a central strategy<strong>for</strong> legal empowerment at <strong>the</strong> local level. In somecountries with particularly weak or oppressivenational governments, community empowermentactivities may be <strong>the</strong> only feasible ones. Wheresocial mobilisation is strong, however, <strong>the</strong> legalempowerment agenda can be built, bottom-up, bysupporting existing initiatives of <strong>the</strong> urban or ruralpoor.Mapping Legal Empowerment beyond<strong>the</strong> Nation StateImplementation undertaken at <strong>the</strong> global levelshould support country-level activities. The importantdifferences among countries and regions call<strong>for</strong> a flexible, demand-driven approach that is appropriateto local realities. The likely focus wouldbe on two types of measures to encourage legalempowerment at <strong>the</strong> country level: advocacy andknowledge management. Advocacy activities wouldfocus on getting key messages out to importanttarget audiences through a variety of vehicles. Awebsite, or a ‘brand/logo’ that can be added toexisting websites, providing updates and progressreports on how <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor agenda is being implemented. An inventoryof evidence on capacity development in domainssimilar to Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor wouldbe compiled, and dialogue would be supported todisseminate global good practices.Knowledge management activities should buildon <strong>the</strong> initial inventories of good practice, on-goinginitiatives and actors engaged in promotingempowerment. A key element is to identify existingindicators and monitoring ef<strong>for</strong>ts that would fur<strong>the</strong>r<strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor agenda. Similarly,and particularly in <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong> rights tojustice and asset holding, evaluations <strong>for</strong> learningwill prove to be valuable.In addition, a range of measures should be undertakento prepare <strong>for</strong> country-level dealings. Countriesand international support organisations canbe identified to support <strong>the</strong> process of change at<strong>the</strong> country level. Pro-poor toolkits and methods tosupport capacity building can be inventoried andgaps identified. These would be made availablethrough a variety of avenues, including websitesand w<strong>ork</strong>shops, among o<strong>the</strong>rs.At <strong>the</strong> regional and sub-regional levels, activitiesshould also likely focus on advocacy and knowledgemanagement. The region and sub-region arecritical <strong>for</strong> success of <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agenda;at <strong>the</strong>se levels global norms can be adaptedto different socio-economic contexts. Buildingpolitical will <strong>for</strong> change will occur through regionaland sub-regional organisations, UN Regional Commissions,sub-regional bodies, and in partnershipwith regional development banks. A series of new‘Regional Social Contracts’ could be an importantmechanism to <strong>for</strong>ge political consensus on <strong>the</strong>legal empowerment agenda.Toolkits and IndicesCarrying out Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor takesa variety of different tools or specific techniques,many of which have been developed by anti-povertyw<strong>ork</strong>ers, community organisers and re<strong>for</strong>m advocatesaround <strong>the</strong> world. These techniques weredesigned to promote activities analogous to <strong>the</strong>poor person’s empowerment agenda of <strong>the</strong> poor,and <strong>the</strong>y include: advocacy/lobbying; collection anddissemination of best practices; community map-279


ping; competencies assessment; conflict preventionand resolution; domestic resource mobilisation;exchanges; focus groups; <strong>for</strong>ce field analysis; genderauditing; impact evaluation; influence mapping;institutional analysis; institutional twinning; internshipprogrammes; <strong>the</strong> logical framew<strong>ork</strong> approach;national symposia; opportunity ranking; mediaoutreach, public hearings and study circles; participatorybudgeting; participatory poverty assessments;translating laws into plain language; political mapping;political will and risk analysis; problem solvingstudies; problem tree analysis; social impact andopportunities assessment; stakeholder monitoringwith household surveys and key in<strong>for</strong>mant interviews;strategic planning framew<strong>ork</strong>; technical assistanceand training on leadership, group w<strong>ork</strong>, andrelated management issues; travel grants/internships<strong>for</strong> officials; web-based support; and w<strong>ork</strong>shops.These tools are general, flexible and easy tomodify; development practitioners shouldreject <strong>the</strong> ones that don’t apply to <strong>the</strong>ir particularcountry context. Critical tasks often include <strong>the</strong>following:• Mobilising stakeholders: Identify key stakeholdersand agree on a process as well as a set ofprinciples that will guide <strong>the</strong> legal empowermentagenda. This should help to build confidenceamong stakeholders. Key issues include coordinationmechanisms, adoption of a protocol oragreement, clarification of roles and responsibilities,and agreement on a broad process <strong>for</strong>re<strong>for</strong>m.• Situation analysis or legal empowerment diagnostic:A detailed assessment should be made of<strong>the</strong> relevant issues to be addressed. The analysiswill identify policy, legal and institutional concerns,as well as gaps in resources, capacity andtools.• Action planning: Development of <strong>the</strong> goal, objectives,strategies, and specific interventions thatcontribute to <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment objective.Critical issues include sequencing and timing,resource constraints, establishing a monitoringand evaluation framew<strong>ork</strong>, and ensuring a balancebetween process and products required tomaintain momentum.• Pilot activities: These should be built around <strong>the</strong>idea of ‘quick wins’ in areas where <strong>the</strong>se are feasible.In this way one can build <strong>the</strong> credibility of<strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agenda and demonstrateinitial success.• Scaling-up: Expanding <strong>the</strong> range of activities andtaking on more complicated challenges. Raisingawareness of past successes, additional sensitisation,and streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong> consultation process.• Institutionalising change and <strong>the</strong> change process:Tackling some of <strong>the</strong> fundamental re<strong>for</strong>msby building on experiences in <strong>the</strong> pilot phase andscaling-up phase to re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> organisations andrules that shape <strong>the</strong> institutional context.Both <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mulation and monitoring phases ofimplementation look to indicators of democratisation,good governance, human rights protection,and many o<strong>the</strong>r variables related to legal empowerment.There are numerous measures of differentaspects of governance in <strong>the</strong> public domain, butun<strong>for</strong>tunately, none is sufficiently developed to beof great value in measuring changes in <strong>the</strong> politicalor legal status of a country’s poor men and womenover time. Accordingly, legal empowerment programmesand projects must develop and use <strong>the</strong>irown metrics <strong>for</strong> evaluating <strong>the</strong> socio-economicenvironment and gauging accomplishments, basedon surveys and interviews.Action planning and progress monitoring are especiallyimportant <strong>for</strong> outside agencies. Among itstools are:• A management in<strong>for</strong>mation system based on280


targeted indicators endorsed by national stakeholders;• Stakeholder monitoring to identify <strong>the</strong> responsesof those that benefited or those that lost from<strong>the</strong> policy re<strong>for</strong>m measures;• Problem-solving studies to devise tailored andpractical solutions to implementation issues;• Process and impact evaluations to support learningover time.The design of each component should respectsome important principles: adaptation to userneeds and availability of resources; user participation;parsimony (<strong>the</strong> least amount of in<strong>for</strong>mationand cost required to accomplish <strong>the</strong> task), andsimplicity. Monitoring of <strong>the</strong> implementation policyre<strong>for</strong>m process will loom large over time, and anumber of practical suggestions that have beengleaned from lessons learned from country experiencesare offered here:• Define a list of steps, processes, targets andmilestone events in <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m process. This willenable <strong>the</strong> breakdown of <strong>the</strong> policy processesinto a series of components to enable an easiergrasp of what needs to be monitored.• Make use of qualitative ra<strong>the</strong>r than quantitativeapproaches in monitoring <strong>the</strong> system, as <strong>the</strong>yoffer a more complete and nuanced set of datathat are numeric and narrative.• Engage implementing parties and beneficiariesin drawing up <strong>the</strong> monitoring systems and methodologiesand acquire feedback. This will simplify<strong>the</strong> process of tracking previously identifiedindicators. Focus group discussions, w<strong>ork</strong>shopsand o<strong>the</strong>r similar methods can be used to ensureparticipation.• Customise <strong>the</strong> choice of monitoring methods to<strong>the</strong> needs and constraints of <strong>the</strong> implementingagencies.• Delegate <strong>the</strong> monitoring process to an externalbody, such as civil society organisations, thinktanks and advocacy groups, to ensure greaterindependence, transparency and accountability.Strategy and TacticsChange agents must put aside preconceived oruni<strong>for</strong>m approaches to empowering <strong>the</strong> poor andthink creatively about how to make policies available,af<strong>for</strong>dable and acceptable. The following corevalues belong front and centre:• Poverty reduction is <strong>the</strong> ultimate objective, soevery re<strong>for</strong>m must be judged by <strong>the</strong> extent towhich it imparts <strong>the</strong> freedom that allows poorpeople to gain more control over <strong>the</strong>ir futuresand to improve <strong>the</strong>ir well-being.• The peaceful struggle against impoverishmentmust be participatory and based on respect <strong>for</strong>human rights, with <strong>the</strong> poor playing active rolesalong <strong>the</strong> way.• Gains of legal empowerment should be broadbasedand take into account <strong>the</strong> diversity ofdisadvantaged groups, especially indigenouspeople who are often inadvertently overlooked bypolicymakers.• Gains also must include women, hence ano<strong>the</strong>rstandard against which to measure Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor policy is whe<strong>the</strong>r it takesfull account of gender-specific effects.• Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> poor in <strong>the</strong> end meanssocial trans<strong>for</strong>mation — not only a more justdistribution of wealth and income, but a moreexpansive sharing of power that enables disadvantagedpeople to begin bringing about significantchange through <strong>the</strong>ir own actions.Anumber of strategic options and considerationsstand out. Although <strong>the</strong>y are rich withparadox, it will be up to government officials, civilsocietymembers, and development practitioners to281


sort out <strong>the</strong> conflicting elements and determine <strong>the</strong>most promising strategic direction to take <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ircommunity, <strong>the</strong>ir country or <strong>the</strong>ir region. We list<strong>the</strong>m as follows:• Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor is easiest toimplement where it is needed least.• A rich base of comparative international experienceexist, but <strong>the</strong>re are no ready-made <strong>for</strong>mulas<strong>for</strong> legal empowerment.• Think systemically, act incrementally.• Think long, go short.• Start from afar, but change from within.• Support associations of <strong>the</strong> poor, but do notcompromise <strong>the</strong>ir independence.• Bundle service delivery.• Support Alternative Dispute Resolution.• Collaborate with professional organisations.Change agents may consider employing <strong>the</strong>se suggestions.While remaining true to <strong>the</strong> core valuesof <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agenda, <strong>the</strong>y may makeit possible <strong>for</strong> many more poor people to improve<strong>the</strong>ir lives in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>eseeable future. Of course,<strong>the</strong>se agents must be prepared to come up againstcountervailing factors, and <strong>the</strong>re can be no guaranteeof successful implementation; but steady andmodest progress in fighting poverty with legal toolsand rights is well within <strong>the</strong> realm of possibility inmost countries.• W<strong>ork</strong> from <strong>the</strong> bottom up and <strong>the</strong> top down.• Decentralise — except when it is better to centralise.• Balance demand <strong>for</strong> change with <strong>the</strong> capacity toaccommodate change.• Put toge<strong>the</strong>r in<strong>for</strong>mal and <strong>for</strong>mal institutions.• Look <strong>for</strong> cooperation, but anticipate confrontation.While walking <strong>the</strong> tightrope of <strong>the</strong>se strategic suggestions,change agents can call upon a variety ofimplementation tactics <strong>the</strong>y can use, including:• Be opportunistic.• Use plain and local language.• W<strong>ork</strong> with para-professionals.• Bring existing technical solutions up to date.• Bring toge<strong>the</strong>r technical expertise and grassrootsexperience.• Dedicate resources to support participatory processesand coordination.• Provide effective outreach.• Provide access to in<strong>for</strong>mation.282


1. Introduction: Attributesof Legal EmpowermentA singularly promising means <strong>for</strong> empowering poorpeople, <strong>the</strong> Commission contends, is to establishlawful claims <strong>the</strong>y can use to lift <strong>the</strong>mselves outof poverty. The four interdependent domains ofempowerment highlighted by <strong>the</strong> Commission are acoherent, accessible legal order; more secure rightsto assets and possessions; stronger and clearerlabour rights; and fairer, more constructive rules <strong>for</strong>small business and micro-enterprise. Each domainis meant to provide defences against exploitationand loss of assets; <strong>the</strong>y fit toge<strong>the</strong>r in a way thatwould w<strong>ork</strong> to emancipate <strong>the</strong> poor to become bothmore productive and better able to keep <strong>the</strong> surpluses<strong>the</strong>y produce.The conceptual framew<strong>ork</strong> is depicted graphicallyin Figure 5.1. Due to insecure land tenure systems,and to <strong>the</strong> unequal distribution of o<strong>the</strong>r factors ofproduction, as well as of economic and politicalpower, <strong>the</strong> poor are shut out from economic opportunities.Voice, identity and assets are <strong>the</strong> key enablingconditions that offer space and leverage to<strong>the</strong> poor to bring <strong>the</strong>ir legal rights to bear in changing<strong>the</strong>ir socio-economic status. Using voice andtaking on stronger identity require both bottom-upand top-down institutional re<strong>for</strong>ms. Membershipbasedorganisations must be built and streng<strong>the</strong>ned,and state policymaking institutions must bemade more inclusive and accountable to <strong>the</strong> poor.Streng<strong>the</strong>ned by voice and identity in <strong>the</strong>ir rolesas citizens, asset holders, w<strong>ork</strong>ers, and entrepreneurs,<strong>the</strong> poor can begin to use <strong>the</strong>ir rights in<strong>the</strong> corresponding empowerment domains to keephold of and grow <strong>the</strong> resources at <strong>the</strong>ir disposal. Ifthings go by design, institutional restructuring andlegal re<strong>for</strong>m will furnish society’s least advantagedmembers with <strong>the</strong> capability to raise <strong>the</strong>ir stature,meet <strong>the</strong>ir basic needs, and eventually move into<strong>the</strong> economic mainstream. Figure 5.1 also showsthat <strong>the</strong> link between <strong>the</strong> enabling conditions andempowerment goes in two directions, and that <strong>the</strong>legal setting both shapes and reflects power relations.Existing political, administrative and juridicalinstitutions have not been fashioned with <strong>the</strong>rights of <strong>the</strong> poor in mind as a major consideration,Figure 5.1 Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> PoorEnabling Conditions Empowerment Domains GoalsVoiceOrganizationRepresentationInstitutionalRe<strong>for</strong>m+}Identity& AssetsCitizensAsset HoldersW<strong>ork</strong>ersEntrepeneurs+LegalRe<strong>for</strong>mExerciseof RightsJusticePropertyLabourBusinessProtectionEconomicOpportunitiesLegalEmpowermentImproved Living Standards283


so <strong>the</strong> Commission is advocating radical changesin <strong>the</strong> existing distribution of public (and private)power. As <strong>the</strong> poor gain income, assets and power,<strong>the</strong>y will be in a stronger position to call <strong>for</strong> additionalinstitutional re<strong>for</strong>m, and so on in a virtuouscycle of empowerment. Changing policies injust one or two legal domains represents a start toempowering <strong>the</strong> poor, but <strong>the</strong> possibilities of legalempowerment will eventually require establishingmore open, inclusive and accountable institutionssystem-wide.This is a bold vision. <strong>Making</strong> it a reality meansimplementing a host of specific publicpolicies around <strong>the</strong> world to tackle <strong>the</strong> everydayhumiliations of powerlessness and destitution.Many legal covenants have been proposed andratified by <strong>the</strong> world community that are reasonablestarting points <strong>for</strong> building inclusive domainsof power 1 — <strong>the</strong> challenge is to adapt <strong>the</strong> broadprinciples of institutional and legal re<strong>for</strong>m to reallife circumstances so <strong>the</strong>y mean something to <strong>the</strong>multitude living on <strong>the</strong> edges of society. Implementationseldom goes as planned, or as <strong>the</strong> Englishproverb has it: ‘There’s many a slip ‘twixt cup andlip.’ This report discusses why those slips systematicallyoccur and how development practitionerscan w<strong>ork</strong> with poor people to sustain momentumduring implementation despite <strong>the</strong> tendency <strong>for</strong>pro-poor policy to be diluted and delayed while beingcarried out.Reports from <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups <strong>for</strong> Chapters 1through 4 have analysed <strong>the</strong> way rights-expandingpolicies in <strong>the</strong> four domains of empowerment canblunt impoverishing <strong>for</strong>ces. Legal recognition is afundamental step so that even <strong>the</strong> poorest citizenscan invoke <strong>the</strong> law to assert <strong>the</strong>ir rights anddemand protections to which <strong>the</strong>y are lawfully entitled.For that to occur, judicial institutions mustbe made responsive, transparent, and answerableto all, not just to <strong>the</strong> privileged few. Property rightsare central to <strong>the</strong> fight against poverty: <strong>the</strong>y are ameans <strong>for</strong> poor people to trans<strong>for</strong>m limited assetsinto secure, productive resources, which <strong>the</strong>ycan <strong>the</strong>n use to enter <strong>the</strong> marketplace and claima fairer share of gains from exchange. Eventually,<strong>the</strong>y could build <strong>the</strong>ir asset base to support a betterquality of life. Labour rights are ano<strong>the</strong>r mechanismby which disadvantaged groups can obtaindecent and productive w<strong>ork</strong>. Such rights enable<strong>the</strong> poor to claim <strong>the</strong>ir rightful share of <strong>the</strong> wealth<strong>the</strong>y have helped to generate and to achieve <strong>the</strong>irhuman potential. Many poor people are caught inambiguous employment relationships where <strong>the</strong>irrights as w<strong>ork</strong>ers are illdefined and <strong>the</strong>ir ability tomake occupations safe and non-abusive is limited.Business rights round out <strong>the</strong> anti-poverty approachtaken by <strong>the</strong> Commission, in view of <strong>the</strong>fact that a significant share of <strong>the</strong> poor are ei<strong>the</strong>rself-employed or already in charge of micro-enterprises.These entrepreneurs are burdened byunnecessarily complicated procedures and regulations,and <strong>the</strong>y lack legal instruments providingaccess to <strong>the</strong> credit markets that would allow <strong>the</strong>mto expand <strong>the</strong>ir small business activities and totake more risks with new investments.It may be evident that <strong>the</strong> interdependent domainsof empowerment are vital to ending poverty, butwe must ask if, and to what extent, <strong>the</strong> underlyingrights are realisable. The question has promptedour w<strong>ork</strong>ing group to address ways of puttingrights-expanding policies in place so <strong>the</strong>y actuallyreach <strong>the</strong> poor. In Section 2, we discuss <strong>the</strong> numerousobstacles that policymakers must face andovercome in ef<strong>for</strong>ts to implement rights-conferringprogrammemes. Understanding <strong>the</strong>se obstacles is<strong>the</strong> first step to overcoming <strong>the</strong>m.284


2. Implementation:Challenges andOpportunitiesImplementation refers to <strong>the</strong> carrying out of publicpolicy. A public policy can be thought of as acourse of action (or purposeful inaction) chosen bypublic authorities to confront a given problem orset of problems. Implementation thus involves governmentor quasi-government organisations settingaside resources and organising specific activities toimprove society in line with announced plans. ForLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor (Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor) <strong>the</strong> relevant policies may includecitizen registration drives, land titling schemes,labour rights <strong>for</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>ers, whe<strong>the</strong>r in enterprises orhome-based, juridical recognition of in<strong>for</strong>mal businesses,and many o<strong>the</strong>r concrete activities.Table 5.1 lists representative specific re<strong>for</strong>msidentified by <strong>the</strong> different w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups that havebeen involved in preparing this volume. They areonly illustrations, and may not necessarily be <strong>the</strong>most pressing required <strong>for</strong> a particular country inachieving legal and institutional change. (For <strong>the</strong>complete record of recommended possible re<strong>for</strong>ms,we refer <strong>the</strong> reader to <strong>the</strong> groups’ separate papersexploring <strong>the</strong> four domains of empowerment.) Itshould be self-evident that <strong>the</strong> policies suggestedin Table 5.1 are not all equally needed or feasible<strong>for</strong> every country. Re<strong>for</strong>mers need to look at <strong>the</strong>Table 5.1 Sample Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor Re<strong>for</strong>msJustice• Effective, af<strong>for</strong>dable and accessible systems of alternate dispute resolution.• Improved identity registration systems, without user fees.• Legal simplifi cation and standardisation and legal literacy campaigns targeting <strong>the</strong> poor.• Stronger legal aid systems and expanded legal service cadres with paralegals and law students.• Structural re<strong>for</strong>m enabling community-based groups to pool legal risks.Property• Legal recognition of joint registration of land rights and re<strong>for</strong>m of discriminatory inheritance and divorce laws andpractices.• Legal guidelines <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>ced relocation, including fair compensation.• Recognition of a variety of land tenure, including customary rights, indigenous people’s rights, group rights, certificates,etc.• State land audits with fi ndings published to discourage illegal taking possession of public land.• Simplifi ed procedures to register and transfer land and propertyLabour• Fundamental rights at w<strong>ork</strong>, especially freedom of association, collective bargaining and non-discrimination.• Improved quality of labour regulation and its en<strong>for</strong>cement.• Inclusive approaches to social protection, delinked from <strong>the</strong> employment relationship. Labour rights (health and safety,hours of w<strong>ork</strong>, minimum income) extended to w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy.• More opportunities <strong>for</strong> education, training and retraining.285


menu of possible Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorre<strong>for</strong>ms to find <strong>the</strong> policies that are applicableto given situations and to particular problems ofpoverty and disempowerment.Implementation sometimes conjures up erroneousimpressions of a chain of command <strong>for</strong> publicpolicy, but this regimented image hides <strong>the</strong>disorderly element of <strong>the</strong> true process. It is best toavoid getting locked into a vision of public policyas a hierarchy of separate stages (one of which isimplementation), and to think instead of interactingspheres of policy activity all of which contributeto implementation. We will navigate this looselyordered process more carefully with <strong>the</strong> policyroadmap in Section 3 of this chapter.Because it is an overarching set of aspirations,covering four mutually supporting domains ofempowerment, Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor itselfis not something that is usually ‘implemented’in <strong>the</strong> narrow sense of <strong>the</strong> term being used here.Implementation entails identifiable projects andprogrammemes in different sectors, and many of<strong>the</strong>se specific courses of government action mightbe empowering in different ways without everbearing <strong>the</strong> official label Legal Empowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor. Seldom is constructive pro-poor policypossible if <strong>the</strong> poor are <strong>the</strong> passive targets of statecentredre<strong>for</strong>m; a balanced legal empowermentstrategy is community-driven and grounded inlocal needs, which, however, can be translated intonational-level re<strong>for</strong>ms <strong>for</strong> wider impact on upwardmobility (Golub 2003).In some cases, <strong>the</strong> positive outcomes <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>poor depend upon government establishing newprocedures or institutions. (An example from <strong>the</strong>Andes countries is given in Box 5.1.) In o<strong>the</strong>rcases, <strong>the</strong> task is to revive an existing policy thatwas never fully or fairly en<strong>for</strong>ced — <strong>for</strong> instance,a bill of rights that calls <strong>for</strong> treating everyone insociety equally. A third possibility <strong>for</strong> aiding <strong>the</strong>Box 5.1 Removing Barriers toPublic W<strong>ork</strong>s ContractsThe development of public investment policies thatpromote <strong>the</strong> use of labour-based technologies hasimproved access of small local contractors to publicprocurement processes <strong>for</strong> services and w<strong>ork</strong>s inAndean countries. Activities range from contractingof micro-enterprises <strong>for</strong> routine road maintenance inrural areas, to involving <strong>the</strong>m in waste collection andstreet cleaning in urban areas. An ILO study shows,however, that access of small local contractors topublic procurement is still very limited due to <strong>the</strong> existenceof a series of legal and institutional barriers.For example, countries may restrict contracts to enterprisesrecorded in <strong>the</strong> national contractor register orto recognised civil engineers or architects.A transparent in<strong>for</strong>mation system about tenders needsto be implemented to facilitate <strong>the</strong> participation ofsmall contractors in public w<strong>ork</strong>s. Two alternativeshave proven w<strong>ork</strong>able: A ‘small contractor card’ and aregister <strong>for</strong> local contractors, enabling small contractorsto carry out small and medium-sized w<strong>ork</strong>s in<strong>the</strong> local area after passing certain prerequisites andminimum qualification criteria. O<strong>the</strong>r possibilitiesinclude: subcontracting consortiums and associativecontracts <strong>for</strong> contractor collaboration; specialcontracting arrangements in projects receiving donorfunding; preferential treatment of micro and smallenterprises in public procurement in Peru; and directcontracting (i.e., one bidder) <strong>for</strong> small contracts.See: José Yeng and Serge Cartier van Dissel,Improving access of small local contractors to publicprocurement — The experience of Andean Countries,ASIST Bulletin #18, ILO (September 2004).poor is to change or eliminate existing policies thathave outlived <strong>the</strong>ir usefulness or that have cometo serve new purposes now at variance with <strong>the</strong>iroriginal intent. Examples of <strong>the</strong> latter are colonialera statutes regarding vagrancy, trespassing and<strong>for</strong>ced labour, many of which survive on <strong>the</strong> booksof many countries. Whatever <strong>the</strong>ir original function,<strong>the</strong>se relics of colonialism have <strong>the</strong> effectof criminalizing poor people. Archaic laws of this286


nature need to be rewritten or abolished to encouragebroad-based legal empowerment.Policy InitiationWhere a public policy originates is <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e aleading factor to consider with implementation.There is also <strong>the</strong> question as to who proposes sucha policy and who <strong>for</strong>mulates <strong>the</strong> approach. Thedegree of domestic enthusiasm and support is whatmatters most <strong>for</strong> implementation, though externaldonors and international agencies are a usefulsource of ideas <strong>for</strong> policy re<strong>for</strong>m. Often, a crisissuch as a natural disaster, or warfare, may act as apowerful stimulus <strong>for</strong> introducing new policies; butit is nei<strong>the</strong>r a necessary nor a sufficient condition<strong>for</strong> implementation. In <strong>the</strong> wake of <strong>the</strong> Asian financialmeltdown in <strong>the</strong> second half of <strong>the</strong> 1990s, <strong>for</strong>instance, Indonesia enacted a series of importantlabour law re<strong>for</strong>ms that began with guaranteeing<strong>the</strong> fundamental right of freedom of association.The first legislative change repealed provisions thatlimited representation to a single government-controllednational federation of trade unions, and putinto place a framew<strong>ork</strong> offering w<strong>ork</strong>ers <strong>the</strong> chanceto <strong>for</strong>m federations as <strong>the</strong>y wished. These re<strong>for</strong>msmight well have been shelved under normal conditions.Building on earlier w<strong>ork</strong> analysing political will<strong>for</strong> anti-corruption activities and on policy re<strong>for</strong>m(Brinkerhoff 2000; Brinkerhoff and Crosby 2002),<strong>the</strong> following initiating scenarios <strong>for</strong> legal empowermentcan be identified:1. Grassroots groups, social movements, membership-basedgroups of w<strong>ork</strong>ers or of small businessowners mobilise and demand change. Some decisionmakers in <strong>the</strong> government respond favourably.This option provides motivation <strong>for</strong> insiders whocan potentially champion change.2.Choice of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>mis based on country actors’ consideration andanalysis of options, anticipated outcomes <strong>for</strong>various groups, and cost/benefits. When countryactors choose policies and actions based on<strong>the</strong>ir own assessments of <strong>the</strong> likely benefits tobe obtained, <strong>the</strong> alternatives and options, and<strong>the</strong> costs to be incurred, <strong>the</strong>n one can crediblyspeak of independently derived preferences andwillingness to act.3.Government initiates Legal Empowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>m. Commitment is questionablewhen <strong>the</strong> initiative <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m comes largely fromexternal actors. Some degree of initiative fromcountry decision-makers must exist in order totalk meaningfully of political will.4.Government mobilises key stakeholders in supportof Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. Thisset up concerns <strong>the</strong> extent to which governmentactors consult with, engage, and mobilise LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor stakeholders. Do decision-makesreach out to members of civil societyand pro-poor groups to advocate <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> changesenvisioned? Are legislators involved? Are <strong>the</strong>reongoing ef<strong>for</strong>ts to build constituencies in favourof new Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>ms?5.Government publicly commits and allocatesresources to Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorre<strong>for</strong>m. To <strong>the</strong> extent that country decision-makersreveal <strong>the</strong>ir Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorpolicy preferences publicly and assign resourcesto achieve announced policy and programmemegoals, such actions indicate commitment tochange. When countries commit to changesfunded by outside donor resources, <strong>the</strong> presenceof political will becomes unclear.6.Government supports continuity of ef<strong>for</strong>t. Ano<strong>the</strong>rsituation is <strong>the</strong> assignment of resourcesand ef<strong>for</strong>t over <strong>the</strong> long-term to achieve LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor goals. One-shot or episodicef<strong>for</strong>ts would signal weak or wavering own-287


ership. Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>ms,by <strong>the</strong>ir very nature, are long-term undertakings.7. Key actors monitor Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor progress <strong>for</strong> learning and adaptation. Itshows a level of commitment when country actorsestablish a system <strong>for</strong> tracking Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>m progress, and activelymanage implementation by adapting to emergingcircumstances over time. However, learning canalso apply to country decision-makers who havebeen able to observe Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor policies, practices, and programmemes fromo<strong>the</strong>r countries and who can selectively adopt<strong>the</strong>m <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir own use.8.Donors club toge<strong>the</strong>r into a joint programmemingstrategy, or multi-donor group (e.g., through <strong>the</strong>Harmonisation Alignment and Coordination approach).This option provides ano<strong>the</strong>r possibility<strong>for</strong> outsiders to assess <strong>the</strong> possibility <strong>for</strong> change.While external support can be a strong catalyst<strong>for</strong> change, external micro-management can alsoeasily render <strong>the</strong> process too burdensome <strong>for</strong>re<strong>for</strong>mers and policy champions within government.It is important that <strong>the</strong> donor role in LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor be supportive and notself-defeating.Be<strong>for</strong>e adopting any of <strong>the</strong>se options, thoughtshould be given as to whe<strong>the</strong>r to engage in severalLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor domains,or sectors, at once, or to proceed with one and<strong>the</strong>n transition to o<strong>the</strong>rs. Also, one must be onguard to ensure that a policy chosen does notsimply increase state power and patronage in waysinconsistent with pro-poor objectives. Agrarianre<strong>for</strong>m has often gone wrong, with <strong>the</strong> supposedbeneficiaries becoming victims. The best guaranteeagainst such perverse developments is to bring <strong>the</strong>poor <strong>the</strong>mselves into <strong>the</strong> policy initiation process.Civil societies, NGOs, membership-based organisationsof employers and of w<strong>ork</strong>ers, coalitions andnetw<strong>ork</strong>s all have a major role to play in generatingand articulating bottom-up demand. The participatoryobjective often goes hand- in-hand withdecentralisation.But <strong>the</strong> advantage of community engagement anddecentralised structures is not a universal law. Insome cases, central authorities may be <strong>the</strong> bestallies <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor, because <strong>the</strong>y can potentiallysidestep local spheres of interest in support ofmarginalized and disadvantaged communities. Theycould serve as counterweight <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor and minoritiesagainst what may be entrenched control oflocal government by anti-poor factions. A concreteexample is <strong>the</strong> key role played by <strong>the</strong> federal governmentof Brazil in combating <strong>for</strong>ced labour in remoterural areas of <strong>the</strong> country (ILO 2001: 25).Policy ChampionsThe degree of initial government support <strong>for</strong> anypolicy derives from domestic leaders who share aperception of a problem and who have agreed onhow to solve it. One or a few of <strong>the</strong>se people mayemerge as policy champions, or entrepreneurs,who make a policy <strong>the</strong>ir signature issue and driveit <strong>for</strong>ward over time. Securing political will <strong>for</strong> anynew course of action needs champions to bringo<strong>the</strong>r government actors on board and precludepolicy spoilers from blocking introduction of <strong>the</strong>policy. Having strong advocates at high levels ofgovernment is vital to getting <strong>the</strong> legislative andexecutive arms to cooperate and follow through onpolicy re<strong>for</strong>m.Policy champions within government may beemboldened by backing and pressure from civilsociety within <strong>the</strong> country. To start a controversialpolicy such as Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor,which threatens many vested interests (see below),domestic policy advocacy is especially important.That is ano<strong>the</strong>r reason why organising by <strong>the</strong> poorand <strong>the</strong>ir representation of <strong>the</strong>ir rights are basic to288


Figure 5.2 Influences on Policy Implementation: Empowering <strong>the</strong> PoorPolicy championsPolicy environment(social structure,economic context,political/administrativesystem, in<strong>for</strong>mality)Policy initiative(intended expansionof justice, assetholding, labourand entrepreneurialrights)Policy stakeholders(beneficiaries, allies,practitioners, challengers)Policy characteristics(complexity, ambiguity,discord)Policy outcomeInstitutional/legalprotection/ opportunities<strong>for</strong> excluded groups<strong>the</strong> Commission’s empowerment agenda.A policy champion can come <strong>for</strong>ward at any levelof government. Many Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor policies do not start out not at <strong>the</strong> nationalcentre, but emerge from <strong>the</strong> periphery via local orregional governments. A mayor or town council, <strong>for</strong>example, may want to take care of problems at anirregular housing settlement, an open air market ora waste disposal site. Acting pro-actively, <strong>the</strong> localgovernment may try to include <strong>the</strong> people wholive or w<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong>se areas in finding <strong>the</strong> solutions.Perhaps more commonly, <strong>the</strong> local government maysimply go ahead with re<strong>for</strong>ms devoid of popularparticipation, sometimes triggering an empoweringreaction as poor men and women move to legallyto protect <strong>the</strong>mselves from <strong>the</strong> harm caused by <strong>the</strong>policy. In ei<strong>the</strong>r scenario, <strong>the</strong> national governmentmay be on <strong>the</strong> sidelines of implementation.Protagonists dedicated to <strong>the</strong> task of implementationmay emerge out of o<strong>the</strong>r stakeholder groups(see below), as well, not just from <strong>the</strong> public sector.Any individual with leadership skills, initiative,and commitment can play <strong>the</strong> role of policy champion,though <strong>the</strong>y may be most effective if <strong>the</strong>yalso have technical knowledge about <strong>the</strong> subject athand. Having several policy champions is generallybetter <strong>for</strong> implementation.Forces Affecting ImplementationOnce a policymaking process has been started, severalcommon factors have been found to facilitateor impede reaching <strong>the</strong> desired policy conclusion,notwithstanding <strong>the</strong> content. Some of <strong>the</strong> generalinfluences on implementation concern <strong>the</strong> peopleaffected by <strong>the</strong> policy, or <strong>the</strong> policy stakeholders.Ano<strong>the</strong>r set of influential factors reflects attributesof <strong>the</strong> context in which <strong>the</strong> policy exists, or <strong>the</strong> policyenvironment. A third set is distinctive featuresor policy characteristics of <strong>the</strong> proposed course ofaction. We can think of <strong>the</strong>se three categories ofsignificant <strong>for</strong>ces as <strong>the</strong> ‘who’, <strong>the</strong> ‘where’, and <strong>the</strong>‘what’ of policy implementation. (The ‘how’ willbe dealt with in Sections 3 and 4, on implementationroadmaps and pro-poor toolkits.) Figure 5.2presents a schematic summary of <strong>the</strong>se influenceson implementation in <strong>the</strong> specific context ofempowering <strong>the</strong> poor. The arrows in Figure 5.2 areshown as diminishing in size during <strong>the</strong> implementationventure, to convey <strong>the</strong> idea that <strong>the</strong>se tend289


to be frictional <strong>for</strong>ces that reduce <strong>the</strong> probabilityof fully attaining projected policy outcomes. Thelarge initiating arrows also assume <strong>the</strong>re is strongpolitical will <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> policy, which may or may notbe true. The frictional influences on implementingLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor will test <strong>the</strong> resourcefulnessof policymakers seeking to carry out<strong>the</strong> Commission’s agenda. Legal Empowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor requires continued vigilance to push backagainst inertia and <strong>the</strong> status quo.Policy StakeholdersA logical place to start when trying to understandinfluences on pro-poor policy implementation is toenumerate <strong>the</strong> stakeholder groups and apprehend<strong>the</strong>ir stand on <strong>the</strong> issue being considered. Stakeholdersare people with an interest in a policy, andwho have <strong>the</strong> capacity to move <strong>the</strong> policy <strong>for</strong>wardor stop it in its tracks. Some of <strong>the</strong>se groups maybe set up as <strong>for</strong>mal entities, while o<strong>the</strong>rs may beunorganised collectives with shared interests butno official representation or recognition. Stakeholdersact out of regard <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir own advantage, as<strong>the</strong>y define it. 2 To implement policy requires a criticalmass of supportive constituencies and minimisationor neutralisation of <strong>the</strong> unsupportive groups.The important thing to bear in mind in lookingat stakeholders is that <strong>the</strong>y act in responseto economic and political incentives. At its core,legal empowerment is about changing incentivesto induce poor people to be more creative andproductive by allowing <strong>the</strong>m greater autonomy andfreedom. Change agents are never<strong>the</strong>less cautionedto be on guard against perverse incentivesthat could lead some constituencies to act in waysdetrimental to poverty reduction.Accordingly, it is advisable to conduct a stakeholderanalysis and to plot stakeholder interests andintentions regarding <strong>the</strong> problem that a particularpolicy seeks to address. 3 There are many possible<strong>for</strong>mats to use with stakeholder analysis, but<strong>the</strong> usual practice is to start by enumerating <strong>the</strong>possible constituencies. Examples from <strong>the</strong> landsector might include <strong>the</strong> following:• Individuals: landowners, landlords, tenants,shareholders, squatters, refugees, as well asbeneficiaries of specific programmemes.• Public sector: politicians, line ministries, provincial/municipal/districtdepartments.• Private sector: land developers, estate agents,notaries, lawyers, surveyors, planners, bankers,media.• Civil society: business associations, NGOs,CBOs, CSOs, faith-based groups, public policyresearch institutes, universities.• Traditional authorities: chiefs, elders.• International development partners: multilateralinstitutions, bilateral agencies, private foundations,international NGOs.The next step, typically, is to estimate eachconstituency’s position on an issue, <strong>the</strong> intensityof its interest in <strong>the</strong> outcome (or policy salience),and <strong>the</strong> group’s relative power to affect <strong>the</strong> outcome.This may be tricky because any given set ofstakeholders need not have monolithic interests.Policy cleavages are important because <strong>the</strong>y affect<strong>the</strong> possibility of building alliances across groups.Also any one member of <strong>the</strong>se groups may belongto several stakeholder categories, and this may alsopresent opportunities <strong>for</strong> communication, bargainingand coalition-building among <strong>the</strong> groups. Ingeneral, it is must be remembered that <strong>the</strong> configurationof stakeholder interests and policy positionsis not static.Sometimes <strong>the</strong> importance of <strong>the</strong> issue to <strong>the</strong>group and its potential influence on implementationmight be rated on a rough zero-to-ten scale(from no importance to vital). The priority to beaccorded <strong>the</strong> group could also be quantified. Table290


Table 5.2 Illustrative Stakeholder MatrixStakeholderInterest in <strong>the</strong>Policy(Pro/Neutral/Con)Salience of <strong>the</strong>Policy(0-10)Influence on <strong>the</strong>Policy(0-10)Priority <strong>for</strong>Policymakers(Hi/Medium/Low)Group 1Group 2Group 3, etc.5.2 shows a generic stakeholder matrix, similarto <strong>the</strong> kind of tool policymakers might develop toidentify potential alliances and implementationstrategies <strong>for</strong> an Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorpolicy initiative.Archon Fung and Erik Wright (2003) suggest twogeneric strategies to contend with stakeholders:top-down adversarial strategies and participatorycollaboration. Building alliances across stakeholdergroups is vital, which will turn on <strong>the</strong> netw<strong>ork</strong>s andcoalitions to which <strong>the</strong>y belong. Support <strong>for</strong> LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor will arise from stakeholderswho view it as good politics and a meansto build political support and legitimacy. Donorscan assist, but <strong>the</strong> driving <strong>for</strong>ces <strong>for</strong> change mustcome from within <strong>the</strong> country. National leadershipin debating <strong>the</strong> difficult issues is crucial.With regard to participatory collaboration, agreementmay be absent about who should be involvedin decisions. Some stakeholders will not have aprearranged structure. Also, <strong>the</strong>re may be no approvedinter-stakeholder process <strong>for</strong> developingcommon policy positions. Such an institutionalarrangement will <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e need to be expresslybrought toge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong> purposes of implementingLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. The challengesof establishing commonly agreed upon definitionsof problem situations and identifying <strong>the</strong> relevantstakeholders must be overcome as a first step.Adversarial situations are even riskier <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor.Most of <strong>the</strong> time, disfavoured, disenfranchisedstakeholders stand to lose in confrontations withbetter endowed groups. Resolution of <strong>the</strong> conflictinginterests ranges along a continuum from negotiationto mediation, to third-party adjudication or arbitration,to refusal to compromise at all. Adversarialstakeholders ordinarily enter into negotiation when<strong>the</strong>y see that is <strong>the</strong> best alternative compared towhat <strong>the</strong>y could obtain ‘away from <strong>the</strong> bargainingtable’ (Ramirez 1999). Where conflict already exists,a strategic starting point <strong>for</strong> development professionalsis to understand stakeholder preferences<strong>for</strong> how to deal with <strong>the</strong> clash of interests.In thinking about stakeholder preferences, <strong>the</strong>reare four stylised stakeholders (shown in <strong>the</strong> middlebox of Figure 5.2, above) to consider: <strong>the</strong> policy’sbeneficiaries, obviously, but also its allies (whosupport <strong>the</strong> policy even though <strong>the</strong>y may notbenefit directly), practitioners responsible <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>policy, and challengers of <strong>the</strong> policy. Some of <strong>the</strong>possibilities are sketched out below; <strong>the</strong>se areillustrative categories and, needless to say, <strong>the</strong>descriptions may not accurately depict any actualgroup in any given country. As noted, real groupsmay straddle <strong>the</strong> generic categories or switch backand <strong>for</strong>th among <strong>the</strong>m, <strong>for</strong> example from beingLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor challengers at onepoint in time to being Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor allies at ano<strong>the</strong>r period.BeneficiariesPoor people are <strong>the</strong> target beneficiaries of LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor policies. They are <strong>the</strong> ma-291


jority of <strong>the</strong> population in many countries. The term‘<strong>the</strong> poor’ is a convenience, of course, <strong>for</strong> this multitudeis far from a monolithic constituency despitesharing hunger, ill health, inadequate housing ando<strong>the</strong>r pathologies of poverty. They live in remote ruralvillages and in urban shantytowns. They w<strong>ork</strong> assubsistence farmers, agricultural labourers, domesticw<strong>ork</strong>ers, street vendors, and trash recyclers. Theyare members of underrepresented ethnic minorities— often internal or external migrants seeking improvedopportunities in a new area where <strong>the</strong>y lackclear legal status. They have been displaced by warand civil unrest, and <strong>the</strong>y are indigenous people whohave been left out and left behind by <strong>the</strong> dominantsociety. A lopsided number of <strong>the</strong> poor are women,who usually have home and family responsibilitieson top of any w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>the</strong>y have found outside <strong>the</strong>home. It is useful to have a segmented census of<strong>the</strong> poor as a starting point <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor w<strong>ork</strong> in any country, to know who <strong>the</strong>yare, where <strong>the</strong>y are located, and to what extent <strong>the</strong>irinterests are aligned.Beneficiaries of legal empowerment need to haveas big a hand as possible in initiating and designing<strong>the</strong> relevant policies. Even though <strong>the</strong>y lackphysical or financial resources, and organisationalresources and social capital in many locales, <strong>the</strong>poor always have a passive capacity to derail legalre<strong>for</strong>ms aimed at <strong>the</strong>m. If <strong>the</strong> poor are afraid of oraverse to playing <strong>the</strong>ir designated role in implementation,<strong>the</strong> best intended policy would cometo nothing. It is critical that <strong>the</strong>ir views be airedand taken into account by policymakers to makesure <strong>the</strong> proposed course of action fits what poorstakeholders are prepared to do.Because poor stakeholders are diverse, legal empowermentplat<strong>for</strong>ms may have surprisingly unevenimpact if officials are inattentive. An illustrationcomes from South Africa. Residents of extra-legalsettlements in South Africa can be given individualdeeds to <strong>the</strong>ir homes. Yet, <strong>for</strong> some inhabitants <strong>the</strong>result is a decrease in security of tenure. Ownershipis registered in <strong>the</strong> name of only one memberof each household, to <strong>the</strong> disadvantage of womenand members of <strong>the</strong> extended family. The newproperty owners also become liable <strong>for</strong> paying localtaxes and service charges, <strong>for</strong>cing some to sell because<strong>the</strong>y cannot af<strong>for</strong>d to pay. A few people who,by statute, come to own dwellings, cannot not livein <strong>the</strong>m because in<strong>for</strong>mal street committees decideo<strong>the</strong>r people should take possession of <strong>the</strong> properties(Cousins et al. 2005). Thus an apparently equitablepolicy to expand asset-holding rights endsup having an unequal impact on poverty, becauseeven within <strong>the</strong>se very poor residential areas, materialgoods and power are not distributed equally.Policymakers might have minimised this outcomeby differentiating among beneficiaries and payinggreater attention to existing social practices thathave widespread legitimacy (see <strong>the</strong> later discussionof in<strong>for</strong>mal institutions).Poor women present a particular challenge <strong>for</strong>Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor because insome cases <strong>the</strong>ir advantage can be to <strong>the</strong> disadvantageof <strong>the</strong> male half of <strong>the</strong> poor population. In EastAfrica, <strong>for</strong> instance, women tend to enjoy ‘use rights’to land (see fur<strong>the</strong>r discussion of <strong>the</strong> spectrum ofland rights, below) as wives and mo<strong>the</strong>rs, but lacktransfer rights due to customs that reserve <strong>the</strong>se <strong>for</strong>men. Women <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e are without secure claim to anatural resource <strong>the</strong>y use <strong>for</strong> daily supplies of fuel,water and food. Legal insecurity inhibits economicprogress because women cannot make decisionson expanding or developing land (UNEP 2004:99).Their fa<strong>the</strong>rs, husbands and sons are likely to balkat ef<strong>for</strong>ts to implement expanded women’s rightsin this important economic realm, because <strong>the</strong>ywould compromise men’s rights to <strong>the</strong> same assets.Women’s community based organisations may be <strong>the</strong>answer. These have proven somewhat effective inpreserving women’s land access in Mexico, though292


effective land control does not necessarily follow(Radel 2005).Poor indigenous people, who represent 15 percentof <strong>the</strong> world’s poor but only 5 percent ofits population (ILO 2007: 27), are ano<strong>the</strong>r specialtest <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor due tophysical or social isolation from <strong>the</strong> influence of<strong>the</strong> governance claimed by a nation-state. Someindigenous people are nomadic; some have beendispossessed de jure or de facto of <strong>the</strong>ir ancestrallands. They may speak a separate language. Indigenouspeople often live in remote sites with higheconomic potential <strong>for</strong> water, timber, or medicinalplants, but lack legal instruments to preventover-extraction of natural resources by outsiders.All <strong>the</strong>se characteristics make it all <strong>the</strong> moreimportant <strong>for</strong> government to reach <strong>the</strong>se wouldbebeneficiaries. (See Box 5.2 <strong>for</strong> an example ofa participatory approach that helped indigenouspeople in Philippines assert claims to <strong>the</strong>ir ancestralrealm.)Box 5.2 Ancestral Domain, Sustainable Development, and ProtectionPlan of <strong>the</strong> Bago and Bugkalot Tribes.The Philippines Indigenous Peoples Rights Act (IPRA) of1997 consolidated bills related to ancestral domains andlands, and international agreements on <strong>the</strong> recognition ofland/domain rights of <strong>the</strong> indigenous peoples. Metagora(a project funded by OECD) in <strong>the</strong> Philippines developedevidence-based assessment methods and tools combiningquantitative and qualitative approaches. Thestudy measures four aspects of <strong>the</strong> rights of indigenouspeoples to <strong>the</strong>ir ancestral domains and lands: <strong>the</strong> indigenouspeoples’ perceptions and awareness of <strong>the</strong>ir rights,<strong>the</strong> enjoyment or violations of <strong>the</strong>se rights, <strong>the</strong> governmentmeasures and customary laws <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> realisationof <strong>the</strong>se rights, and <strong>the</strong> availability of mechanisms <strong>for</strong>redressing violations or fulfilling rights.Metagora’s method of w<strong>ork</strong> is based on a bottom-up approachconsisting of:• W<strong>ork</strong>ing with <strong>the</strong> shareholders in pilot countries, toidentitfy issues in human rights, democracy; andgovernance <strong>for</strong> which evidence-based assessment ishighly relevant;• Applying statistical methods and tools to that particularcontext;• Assessing <strong>the</strong>se methods <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir capacity to providepolicy relevant results;• Providing stakeholders with a shared knowledge on <strong>the</strong>policy issues at stake; drawing universal lessons from<strong>the</strong> local experiences;• Formulating recommendations <strong>for</strong> fur<strong>the</strong>r applicationof <strong>the</strong> tested methods elsewhere.Three tribes covering public ancestral domains in threeregions of <strong>the</strong> Philippines were covered by <strong>the</strong> survey.Major respondents were representative samples of <strong>the</strong>tribal population stratified according to selected criteriathat are in consonance with <strong>the</strong> customs and traditionsof <strong>the</strong> target population. Non-indigenous people respondents,especially <strong>the</strong> governance stakeholders, alsocomprised <strong>the</strong> secondary respondents of <strong>the</strong> survey.This is a case of objective survey data having policy <strong>for</strong>ceon account of <strong>the</strong> involvement of an international projectin partnership with <strong>the</strong> Commission on Human Rights of<strong>the</strong> Philippines, its Regional Offices, <strong>the</strong> National Commissionon Indigenous People, and National StatisticalCoordination Board (NSCB).The data and evidence ga<strong>the</strong>red had <strong>the</strong> positive consequenceof making <strong>the</strong> national and regional governmentauthorities take <strong>the</strong> implementation of <strong>the</strong> provisions of<strong>the</strong> Philippines Indigenous Peoples Rights Act seriously,so that <strong>the</strong> rights of indigenous peoples are settled, aproactive public policy approach is taken, and fundsprovided under <strong>the</strong> law are allocated properly to benefit<strong>the</strong> indigenous people.Source: Metagora Training Materials. Ref:http://www.metagora.org.293


At <strong>the</strong> national level, a society’s failure to provideopportunities to all in an ethnically diverse population(poor and not-poor alike) is found in somestudies to be a drag on economic per<strong>for</strong>mance,making it harder <strong>for</strong> a country to grow its way outof poverty (ILO 2007: 9-10). Policymakers need toconsider how ethnic and religious cleavages within acountry, along with traditional caste or gender-basedexclusions and oligarchic traditions of domination,affect <strong>the</strong> distribution of wealth and income, and<strong>the</strong> projected likelihood of empowering re<strong>for</strong>ms.These power relations may have a significant impacton <strong>the</strong> chances of implementing Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor. We return to <strong>the</strong> questions of <strong>the</strong>economic and social context later in Section 2.AlliesThe main allied stakeholders of Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor policies are pro-poor communityassociations and activists of civil society. Someof <strong>the</strong>se stakeholders will be local social actionor advocacy groups, such as <strong>the</strong> Indonesian LegalAid Foundation whose mission is to defend poorpeople in court and expand <strong>the</strong>ir rights. Allies mayalso include professional associations sympa<strong>the</strong>ticto <strong>the</strong> plight of <strong>the</strong> excluded and have-nots. Forexample, Ecuador’s Association of <strong>Law</strong> SchoolDeans supports legal assistance <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> indigent inthat country. National bar associations are engagedin similar activities in many nations.Certain politicians may come out as allies. It is notuncommon, <strong>for</strong> example, to find even somewhatdisreputable politicians offering to use public landto woo voters’ support in slum areas. Such personsmay not be reliable allies, however. More dependablewill be <strong>the</strong> genuine policy champions, who haveemerged from among <strong>the</strong> national or local politicalleadership to make a progressive name <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>mselvesas friends of legal empowerment.Some commercial enterprises, and particularlylarger companies and multinational corporations,may fall into <strong>the</strong> camp of policy allies on certainoccasions. Over 3,000 corporations in morethan 100 countries have joined <strong>the</strong> UN’s GlobalCompact, which commits <strong>the</strong>m to support highstandards in <strong>the</strong> areas of <strong>the</strong> environment, humanrights and labour rights (UN 2007). These firmsoften say <strong>the</strong>y would like to <strong>for</strong>ge partnerships withpoor communities in <strong>the</strong> developing world to createbusiness models that are sustainable, equitableand embedded in <strong>the</strong> local culture (Hart 2005).Some signatories are turning to <strong>the</strong> poor as businesspartners, suppliers, or distributors.Nairobi, <strong>for</strong> example, has a productive alliancebetween in<strong>for</strong>mal entrepreneurs and larger businesses.Two business associations joined with <strong>the</strong>street vendors’ organisation in a dialogue with localauthorities to improve <strong>the</strong> status of street vending.Street vendors in Kenya’s capital city are subject toharassment and demand <strong>for</strong> bribes from city inspectors.The uncertainty <strong>for</strong>ces <strong>the</strong> vendors to limit <strong>the</strong>irstock and hinders <strong>the</strong>ir productivity and income. Thetwo conventional associations had wanted to driveout street vending because of litter and crowding,but came around because, among o<strong>the</strong>r things, ofa growing realisation that <strong>the</strong> outdoor presence ofvendors limits crime and thus is good <strong>for</strong> everyone’sbusiness. Interestingly, <strong>the</strong> vendors’ group wants itsmembers to pay licensing fees, on <strong>the</strong> argument thatpaying gives <strong>the</strong> members legal cover and providesleverage <strong>for</strong> government services (Kamunyori 2007).It should go without saying that <strong>the</strong>se observationsdo not mean every self-described ally of <strong>the</strong> pooris a true friend of <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agenda.The real world is far more subtle and complex thanthat. Some grassroots groups may feel threatenedby Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor if <strong>the</strong>y do nothave <strong>the</strong> lead in directing <strong>the</strong> movement. Stakeholderanalysis cannot be done by mechanisticallyapplying generic labels to pre-determined groups of294


actors and assuming <strong>the</strong>y will behave according to<strong>the</strong>ir category.PractitionersA third important set of generic stakeholders arepractitioners — mainly <strong>the</strong> government officials,court officers, and o<strong>the</strong>rs who draft, interpretand administer <strong>the</strong> land laws, labour statutesand commercial regulations in a country. Despitesometimes having low positions in <strong>the</strong> bureaucratichierarchy of government, <strong>the</strong>se officials can and dowield considerable effective discretionary authorityover implementation.One common problem is that permits, businesslicenses, tax assessments and <strong>the</strong> likeare sources of power and potential illegal incomethrough bribes, kickbacks and o<strong>the</strong>r ‘rent-seeking’behaviour. 4 Even <strong>the</strong> abstruse text describing manyof <strong>the</strong>se regulations provides low-level governmentemployees with power, <strong>for</strong> citizens cannot decode legaljargon easily on <strong>the</strong>ir own. The interests and attitudesof government officials at all levels must <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>ebe factored into <strong>the</strong> implementation process. InBeijing, <strong>for</strong> example, law en<strong>for</strong>cement officers andlocal authorities look <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r way when rural-urbanmigrant entrepreneurs do not comply fully withlicense requirements and instead lease licenses illegallyfrom local residents. This illicit license-leasingpractice is sustained because bureaucrats profit fromit (He 2005). Streamlining <strong>the</strong> business registrationprocess in line with Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorgoals would threaten illegal but routine bureaucraticincome in China’s capital city.These comments do not imply that bureaucrats arealways spoilers of re<strong>for</strong>m. A new programmeme mayalso mean that staff members gain promotions,have interesting new responsibilities, or have trainingopportunities or o<strong>the</strong>r perquisites. Within everygovernment executive agency or judicial institution<strong>the</strong>re may be potential policy champions, who cometo identify with a particular solution to a socialproblem and make strenuous ef<strong>for</strong>t to get it implemented.As noted, entrepreneurial ef<strong>for</strong>t by policychampions in elected and administrative office is aconsistent <strong>the</strong>me in successful policy implementationaround <strong>the</strong> world.ChallengersA final constituency to consider is rival stakeholdersthat challenge disenfranchised people exercisingnew rights or reviving latent ones. These competingor oppositional stakeholders may include <strong>for</strong>eignbusinesses and large domestic companies, but alsocover many small landlords, mine owners, shopkeepers,and moneylenders, plus some lawyers,engineers, and similar specialised experts who tendto prefer <strong>the</strong> status quo. We should be careful aboutbrushing any class of people with too broad a stroke,but numerous local elites and professionals arelikely to feel threatened by confident and <strong>for</strong>cefulpoor people and may try to pre-empt improvementsin poor people’s status and income. <strong>Law</strong>yers, <strong>for</strong>example, may lose <strong>the</strong> upper hand with clients iflaws are translated into everyday language or if inexpensiveconflict resolution <strong>for</strong>ums are made widelyavailable.A common and tricky problem of implementation iswhen contending stakeholders do not try to block re<strong>for</strong>msoutright, but subtly manipulate emerging policies(and especially donor-driven programmemes)to <strong>the</strong>ir advantage — a phenomenon known as ‘elitecapture’ (Decker 2005). This distortion is chronicwith Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor activities.In many Asian countries, <strong>for</strong> example prospectivetitling programmemes often have <strong>the</strong> perverse effectof inducing speculators to buy up land ahead oftime from squatters at slightly better than in<strong>for</strong>malprices. The squatters come out ahead in <strong>the</strong> shortterm, but pay <strong>the</strong> opportunity cost of not waitinglong enough to get <strong>the</strong> main benefit of <strong>the</strong> titling295


programme — which accrues to <strong>the</strong> people withdeeper pockets. Low income and vulnerability leadto a safety-first calculation, so squatters reasonablyprefer to have <strong>the</strong>ir cash immediately. Contrary to<strong>the</strong> stated intention of <strong>the</strong> titling programmeme,however, elites capture most of <strong>the</strong> gains from it.The sequential and conditional release of funds isone strategy <strong>for</strong> countering <strong>the</strong> persistent problem ofelite capture (Platteau 2004).Policy Environment and ContextualAnalysisCrucial as stakeholders are to implementation,even more basic is <strong>the</strong> country context. In mostcountries, a minority of <strong>the</strong> better-off holds disproportionateinfluence over <strong>the</strong> local and nationalpolicy apparatus due to its more sophisticatedknowledge about markets, to its greater businessand political contacts, and to its better access tofinance. These power structures influence <strong>the</strong> decisionson who prevails in <strong>the</strong> bargaining, competitionand cooperation among stakeholders, and alsoconstrain many o<strong>the</strong>r facets of Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor. It is impossible to decide what sorts ofre<strong>for</strong>ms to attempt and to determine what it will totake to carry <strong>the</strong>m without first coming to an honestassessment of <strong>the</strong> country policy environment.A clear-eyed contextual analysis should <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>eguide all decisions on if, when and how to go <strong>for</strong>wardwith Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor policiesand provide guidance during implementation. AsFigure 5.2 suggests, <strong>the</strong> most important constraintsset by <strong>the</strong> national socio-political context are:• The domestic social structure, especially itsgender, class and ethnic makeup, plus culturalattitudes toward participation and equality.• The economic context — including <strong>the</strong> distributionof wealth and income, and <strong>the</strong> level and rateof economic growth.• The characteristics of <strong>the</strong> state — both <strong>the</strong> politicaland <strong>the</strong> administrative system.• The extent of economic and political in<strong>for</strong>malityand tensions with <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal and officially recognisedsystems.These are <strong>the</strong> critical factors <strong>for</strong> contextual analysisand <strong>the</strong> parameters within which practitionersmust operate as <strong>the</strong>y try to steer implementation oflegal empowerment re<strong>for</strong>ms.Social StructureSeveral important points regarding social structurewere already implied in <strong>the</strong> discussion of stakeholders,which emphasised <strong>the</strong> task of buildingwinning coalitions <strong>for</strong> change among clashingconstituencies. Thus, a country with fewer poorpeople relative to its population will likely find iteasier to integrate <strong>the</strong>m into <strong>the</strong> legal and economicsystem compared to a country with morepoor people (though <strong>the</strong> poor also may be easierto ignore when <strong>the</strong>ir numbers are lower). Similarly,a homogeneous country will also find empoweringpeople at <strong>the</strong> bottom takes less ef<strong>for</strong>t compared toa country where <strong>the</strong> population is deeply divided bylanguage, religion or national origin. The absolutegap between rich and poor also matters, with asmaller gap facilitating implementation of LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor policies. A society wherewomen have considerable legal recognition willhave less ground to make up with empowering poorwomen than ano<strong>the</strong>r society. Whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> socialand economic cleavages are cumulative or crosscutting(that is, to what extent does membershipin a particular religious community or ethnic groupcorrelate with discrimination, low income, exclusionfrom power, and o<strong>the</strong>r negative attributes).These are given social facts at any point in time,though <strong>the</strong>y can change in a country due to economicgrowth, human migration, mass education,and exposure to media, among o<strong>the</strong>r factors. Poli-296


cymakers must tailor <strong>the</strong>ir empowerment strategiesto <strong>the</strong> structure of particular societies.Cultural factors are crucial to <strong>the</strong> social structure,as well. Assorted traditions and customarypractices colour <strong>the</strong> systems of propertyrights, contract en<strong>for</strong>cement and dispute resolutionthat <strong>the</strong> poor typically use. Indigenous people areparticularly likely to have elaborate but officiallynon-existent systems in place <strong>for</strong> organising economiclife. There may be a large gap here between<strong>the</strong> shared norms and values of <strong>the</strong> beneficiaries oflegal empowerment versus <strong>the</strong>ir stakeholder allies(not to mention <strong>the</strong>ir rivals or opponents). Thatcultural distance makes it harder to come up withw<strong>ork</strong>able and effective empowerment instrumentsand activities (see additional discussion on in<strong>for</strong>malinstitutions, below).Ano<strong>the</strong>r important social structure consideration isthat many societies and subcultures reflect hierarchicaland patriarchal power structures that mayimpinge on implementation of legal empowerment,which is predicated on broad participation of <strong>the</strong>beneficiaries in decisions and <strong>the</strong> levelling effectsof economic rights. Great tact may be needed tofind socially acceptable yet effective means ofinvolving, say, women or members of historicallyexcluded minorities in choosing and implementingpolicies that expand <strong>the</strong> ambit of empowerment.Development practitioners need to pay close attentionto <strong>the</strong>se cultural factors when <strong>the</strong>y considerhow to carry out Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor.Economic contextA country’s social structure cannot be isolated inpractice from who holds <strong>the</strong> country’s wealth andexercises economic power. The distribution patternmay reflect historical injustice whereby a privilegedfew used <strong>the</strong>ir political influence and access to<strong>the</strong> justice system to legitimise unfair claims toproperty. The more unequal <strong>the</strong> initial pattern ofownership of land, capital, and o<strong>the</strong>r productiveassets, <strong>the</strong> more cautious will re<strong>for</strong>mers have to beabout regularising <strong>the</strong> system of economic rights.There is no advantage to <strong>the</strong> poor from locking inplace deep pre-existing inequities in proprietorship— though to correct those inequities compensationmust usually be paid to <strong>the</strong> pre-existing assetholders, which may be both financially costly andpolitically risky due to <strong>the</strong> resistance it is likely tospark. It is important to <strong>the</strong> Commission’s agendathat Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>ms aredesigned in a manner that braces <strong>the</strong> claims of<strong>the</strong> poor to assets without amplifying <strong>the</strong> existingskewed allocation of property.Land is probably <strong>the</strong> most difficult economicresource to manage, both because its supply islimited and because so many poor people dependdirectly on land <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir survival. Indigenouspeoples, and pastoralist and subsistence farmersmust assure <strong>the</strong>ir use of <strong>for</strong>ests, pastures andarable fields, but, as mentioned earlier, that brings<strong>the</strong>m into head-on conflict with richer claimantsto <strong>the</strong> same limited resources. Land re<strong>for</strong>ms haveproven a conundrum in many countries due to <strong>the</strong>expense and complexity of managing overlappingclaims to <strong>the</strong> identical resource.In addition to how a nation’s ‘economic pie’ isdivided up, <strong>the</strong> overall size of <strong>the</strong> ‘pie’ also influences<strong>the</strong> extent of absolute poverty and hence <strong>the</strong>urgency of poor people’s empowerment and <strong>the</strong>scale of <strong>the</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>t needed to confront that socialproblem. Economic growth makes it easier to redistributeassets to <strong>the</strong> poor, yet, ironically, growth isalso an unsettling <strong>for</strong>ce <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor.Acase in point is redevelopment of <strong>the</strong> vastsquatter settlement of Dharavi, in Mumbai,India. As <strong>the</strong> land has soared in value, <strong>the</strong> city andstate have advanced plans to replace <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maltownship with upscale development. Because297


Dharavi’s residents lack ownership rights <strong>the</strong>ir abilityto defend <strong>the</strong>ir homes and shops is limited. Fortunately,direct action and advocacy from civil societyhas gotten <strong>the</strong> government to agree to provide smallapartments to <strong>the</strong> residents who will be displaced.That is not <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> story, however. Theseredevelopment plans can be drawn up without anyconsultation, and it is unclear who within Dharavi’spopulation will get <strong>the</strong> new living units and w<strong>ork</strong>sites. Mumbai has sky-high real estate prices and<strong>the</strong> state and <strong>the</strong> private developers still stand toearn huge amounts over and above <strong>the</strong> cost of thismitigation ef<strong>for</strong>t (Patel 2007). On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand,mitigation may not have been <strong>for</strong>thcoming at allwere it not <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> dynamic economic conditions inMumbai.With <strong>the</strong> clear exception of many programmemesinvolving <strong>the</strong> transfer of land andproperty, <strong>the</strong> financial cost of empowerment programmemesmay be modest. Since some elementsof Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor are revenueneutral, it is possible to pick <strong>the</strong> resource neutralelements first, or else <strong>the</strong> ones that require limitedexpenditure of resources. Special attention shouldbe paid to low-cost ways to en<strong>for</strong>ce property rights,guarantee contracts, and provide fair resolutionof business and commercial disputes. Still, even<strong>the</strong>se activities will slow to a crawl if <strong>the</strong> countrydoes not find enough funds to pay <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>m.Empowering <strong>the</strong> poor is a long-time endeavor soongoing budget support is problematic. Take manyof <strong>the</strong> emerging market economies in Asia. Theystill frequently underpay <strong>the</strong>ir judges and allow<strong>the</strong>ir courts to languish with inadequate facilities.Many of <strong>the</strong>se legal systems are swampedwith a backlog of cases and are widely accused ofcorruption. Hence, fast economic growth does notnecessarily put an end to resource scarcities <strong>for</strong>implementation if change is not a high priority.Political SystemPolitical system variables (i.e., factors affecting<strong>the</strong> demand side of government) are crucial <strong>for</strong>implementation and need to be taken apart andlooked at carefully. To combat legal disempowerment,<strong>the</strong>re is no substitute <strong>for</strong> collective action bypoor men and women to push <strong>for</strong> rights and protections,as in <strong>the</strong> Mumbai case cited above. Whendoing contextual analysis, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, practitionersmust consider whe<strong>the</strong>r farmers, residents, w<strong>ork</strong>ers,consumers and o<strong>the</strong>r constituencies have legalprotection to organise and petition <strong>the</strong> governmentor bargain with private entities to redress <strong>the</strong>irgrievances. In countries where <strong>the</strong>se basic rightsare neglected or suppressed, Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor will be harder to carry out. The right toorganise does not exist in a vacuum separated fromactual organisations, and thus <strong>the</strong> level of developmentof civil society is ano<strong>the</strong>r important influenceon <strong>the</strong> diagnosis <strong>for</strong> policy implementation.It is easier to carry out Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor in countries with strong community organisations,occupational membership groups or pro-poorpolitical parties, than where such social capital isabsent.As we have stressed, implementation of Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor usually involves communityparticipation, sometimes through <strong>for</strong>mal venues setup <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> purpose or else through <strong>the</strong> establishedmechanisms of local government. Simply makingparticipatory procedures available, however,is not sufficient because <strong>the</strong> better-off and moreconnected members of communities tend to takeadvantage of <strong>the</strong>m. Barbara Pozzoni and NaliniKumar (2005) describe two related <strong>for</strong>ms of socialexclusion: <strong>for</strong>mal, which refers to <strong>the</strong> poor anddisadvantaged not showing up at meetings, andsubstantive, which refers to <strong>the</strong>ir not speaking upin <strong>the</strong>se venues. In India, <strong>for</strong> example, local selfgovernmentappears to be w<strong>ork</strong>ing reasonably well,298


ut some community members report being toointimidated to contradict local leaders and governmentadministrators (Viswanathan and Srivastava2007: 72). Social mobilisation of <strong>the</strong> poor canhelp make participatory procedures in governmentw<strong>ork</strong> closer to <strong>the</strong> way <strong>the</strong>y are meant to.Legal empowerment is sometimes also facilitatedby democratic competition and free discussionof policy issues at <strong>the</strong> national level, whichinduces leaders seeking majority support to viewith policy proposals favourable to disadvantagedcitizens. But <strong>the</strong>se are not panaceas. Proceduraldemocratic rule is now quite common in <strong>the</strong> world,yet empirical studies show countries experiencingdemocratic re<strong>for</strong>m do not have systematicallybetter poverty outcomes (Ross 2006). For example,democratic countries are just as capable asdictatorships at carrying out government austerityprogrammemes that fall most heavily on <strong>the</strong> poor(Lindenberg and Devarajan 1993).The procedural democracies are not at all consistentin <strong>the</strong> extent to which <strong>the</strong>y protect minorities,root out political corruption and preventstate-sponsored violence against citizens. Often<strong>the</strong> leadership positions in <strong>the</strong>se countries aredominated by <strong>the</strong> same social stratum that was incharge be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong> advent of procedural democracyand competitive politics. In some societies thisdominant group’s role is legitimated by religionor tradition, and deferential attitudes on <strong>the</strong> partof <strong>the</strong> poor may add ano<strong>the</strong>r stumbling block toempowerment. One explanation <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> economicdisparities that persist under democracy is <strong>the</strong>holdover of identity politics that divide <strong>the</strong> poor(Varshnay 2005). There may also be deep rootedpatron-client netw<strong>ork</strong>s that push down <strong>the</strong> poor(more on this topic later).Take <strong>the</strong> example of Philippines. Its governmentis chosen in contested elections. Thousands ofcommunity based organisations exist in Manila andelsewhere, so <strong>the</strong>re is a strong civil society. Philippineshas a national housing finance programmemeto regularise <strong>the</strong> city’s vast in<strong>for</strong>mal settlements,implementation of which is left to partnershipsbetween community groups, local governments,and <strong>the</strong> private sector. Local governments are alsorequired to set aside land <strong>for</strong> relocation of in<strong>for</strong>malsettlers and to compile lists of in<strong>for</strong>mal settlers whoare eligible <strong>for</strong> relocation. Yet even in this relativelybenign political environment, <strong>the</strong> community groupstend to have limited influence and evictions andconversion of land to commercial uses continuesapace (Shatkin 2000).Honduras and Nicaragua have analogous problemsin rural areas. Land and <strong>for</strong>estry laws favour <strong>the</strong>poor on paper, but practice is different. In Nicaragua,constitutional and legislative provisionsexist <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> demarcation and titling of indigenousterritories. Yet <strong>the</strong> government continues to grantindustrial logging concessions on community landswithout fulfilling <strong>the</strong>se requirements. In Honduras,small-scale <strong>for</strong>est producers have use rights butseldom can meet transaction costs of securingpermits and o<strong>the</strong>r approvals, owing to regulatorycomplexity and bureaucratic corruption. This <strong>for</strong>ces<strong>the</strong>m to rely on timber traders to secure permitsand o<strong>the</strong>r approvals, which, in turn, fuels collusionbetween traders and public officials, and elite captureof community <strong>for</strong>est management rights (Wellset al. 2004). Again, <strong>the</strong> quality of democraticinstitutions in this pair of countries appears to varyaccording to <strong>the</strong> class and income of <strong>the</strong> citizensusing <strong>the</strong>m.These anecdotes obviously do not mean dictatorshipsare consistently better at confronting povertythan are countries classified as democratic. Thereare examples throughout history of authoritarianregimes that carried out successful land re<strong>for</strong>ms ando<strong>the</strong>r pro-poor policies; yet <strong>the</strong>re have undoubtedly299


een a far greater number of authoritarian regimesthat did little or nothing to improve <strong>the</strong> health andwell-being of ordinary citizens. We need to look beyondpolitical labels when designing implementationstrategies <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor.It is important to think of political systems asshades of grey when it comes to empowering <strong>the</strong>poor. At <strong>the</strong> far end of <strong>the</strong> pallet are systems ofarbitrary personal rule, which are typically quiteclosed regarding grassroots participation in policymaking,but which may be open to pro-poor policiesif <strong>the</strong> regime is a populist one that depends onmass support. Dictatorships blend into more openand competitive systems where <strong>the</strong> poor may haveprogressively greater scope to sway public policy,but where <strong>the</strong> rich may still exercise hegemony onkey political economy issues. Happily, <strong>the</strong>re arefewer political systems today where poor peoplecannot organise at all to have some countervailinginfluence on government decisions; but in anumber of countries, freedom of association isstill being denied (ILO 2004: 1-2). And even in<strong>the</strong> most receptive political systems <strong>the</strong> influenceof <strong>the</strong> poor is difficult to trans<strong>for</strong>m into extensivepower. Development practitioners should be carefulnot let preconceptions about regimes blind <strong>the</strong>m to<strong>the</strong>se possibilities.Administrative stateThe supply side of political systems also needs tobe considered to understand implementation probabilities.How capable is <strong>the</strong> public administration?Does <strong>the</strong> state have <strong>the</strong> capacity to provide physicalsafety, to secure personal belongings, to settledisputes fairly, and to provide o<strong>the</strong>r public goodsto society? Does it possess <strong>the</strong> personnel, skills,systems, and infrastructure to carry out <strong>the</strong>se corefunctions? Even political will cannot drive re<strong>for</strong>min <strong>the</strong> face of binding constraints on <strong>the</strong> capacityof institutions charged with delivering <strong>the</strong> mandateof empowerment. High-capacity states are onesthat implement policies efficiently, predictably, andin <strong>the</strong> manner intended. High-capacity states mayor may not be democratic, but <strong>the</strong>y can carry out<strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor agenda if thatis what <strong>the</strong> leadership wants. In very low-capacitystates, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, supportive leadership isstill beneficial except <strong>the</strong> follow-through capabilityis missing. Residents must <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e improvise andfigure out how to protect assets and resolve disputesthrough pragmatic means, such as aligningwith a political patron (see discussion of in<strong>for</strong>malgovernance below).Administrative weakness is usually rooted in lackof human and financial resources, but a viciouscycle rein<strong>for</strong>ces <strong>the</strong> problem. A World Bank reportargues: Burdensome or extraneous business andlabour market official regulations drive people into<strong>the</strong> shadow economy, while a collective perceptionof ineffectiveness of <strong>the</strong> state’s actions gives riseto a social norm of non-compliance with taxes andregulations, which fur<strong>the</strong>r undermines <strong>the</strong> state’scapacity to en<strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> law and to provide publicservices (Perry et al. 2007). However, <strong>the</strong> methodologyunderlying such studies has come under serioustechnical criticism (Berg and Cazes, 2007).Bureaucratic corruption can also be a major weakeningfactor, especially <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor who lack <strong>the</strong>wherewithal to pay bribes to make things happenwithin <strong>the</strong> bureaucracy. For people with means, on<strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong> civil service may seem capableenough because, unlike <strong>the</strong> poor, <strong>the</strong>y can pay <strong>for</strong>individualised special treatment. Thus bureaucraticcorruption will tend to rein<strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> existingconfiguration of wealth and power. In cases wherepublic sector wages are low and virtually everything<strong>the</strong> civil service does is <strong>for</strong> sale, it may be almostimpossible <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor to get public administrationto w<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong>ir favour. Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor re<strong>for</strong>mers would have to address corruption300


e<strong>for</strong>e taking on implementation, or choose to w<strong>ork</strong>in sectors where government employees are moreprofessional and trustworthy. 5Attitudes of public servants are also significant.Receptivity of state institutions to <strong>the</strong> agenda oflegal empowerment is as much about changing <strong>the</strong>bureaucratic mindset as it is about new processesor additional resources. Too often public functionaries<strong>for</strong> a variety of reasons lack a service orientationand see <strong>the</strong>ir job as an entitlement. This mustbegin to change to implement Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor.Again we are talking about shades of capacity, notstark monochromatic differences. Among developingand transitional countries, those with highernational incomes tend to be recognised as having<strong>the</strong> stronger administrative capability, though <strong>the</strong>reare certainly exceptions to this pattern. The leastdeveloped countries, especially small island nationsand land-locked countries tend to have lowercapacity as a rule. Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Pooris obviously easiest to carry out on a national scalein countries with better capacity.State capacity is at its nadir in countries wherecentral authority is so ineffective that it has lost oris losing practical control over much of its territory.Implementing Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor in<strong>the</strong>se political systems must be done entirely from<strong>the</strong> bottom up or <strong>the</strong> outside in, because <strong>the</strong> nationalgovernment is too dysfunctional to w<strong>ork</strong> from <strong>the</strong>top down. Consider <strong>the</strong> extreme case of Somalia,with four overlapping judicial structures: a <strong>for</strong>malone in regional administrations and central governmentscreated at international peace processes, atraditional, clan-based system, a growing numberof Muslim shari’a courts in urban areas, and ad hocmechanisms established by militias (Le Sage 2005:7). A nationwide implementation strategy <strong>for</strong> legalempowerment is currently problematic in Somalia,though <strong>the</strong>re may be local or regional space <strong>for</strong>Box 5.3 Empowering W<strong>ork</strong>ersthrough CommunityContracting‘As in many o<strong>the</strong>r places in Somalia, <strong>the</strong> civil war thathas been raging on <strong>for</strong> years has had its toll on Garowe,a city in <strong>the</strong> Puntland region of that country. … A projectto improve <strong>the</strong> livelihoods of <strong>the</strong> people of Garowe throughsustainable waste collection management … applied <strong>the</strong>Community Contracting Model, a participatory processwhereby <strong>the</strong> community group negotiates with local governmentor a development programmeme and enters intocontractual agreements to undertake garbage collectionand disposal. This had multiple advantages: members of<strong>the</strong> community were directly involved in negotiating contractswhich in turn provided <strong>the</strong>m with jobs that helped<strong>the</strong>m improve <strong>the</strong>ir livelihoods.’‘This contracting system uses a participatory andbottom-up approach…. Local actors were responsible<strong>for</strong> … organising community contributions, transporthire, procurement of tools and materials, authorizationof payments, decisions on w<strong>ork</strong>ers’ wages, selection andsupervision of w<strong>ork</strong>ers and ensuring w<strong>ork</strong>ers’ safety. Theywere also responsible <strong>for</strong> solving all disputes related toproject implementation.’‘There is a great potential <strong>for</strong> replication of sustainablewaste management activities in towns and municipalitieswithin <strong>the</strong> country as well as in urban centres ofo<strong>the</strong>r African countries.’ UN-Habitat, ILO and UNA (anItalian consortium of NGOs) have supported <strong>the</strong> Somaliinitiative.Indeed, 11 municipalities in Kenya, Tanzania and Ugandaare pursuing similar approaches to municipal service delivery.Community-based organisations, small enterprises,NGOs, in<strong>for</strong>mal economy operators and local traininginstitutions w<strong>ork</strong> with <strong>the</strong> administration to create propoorurban services using public-private partnerships.This was made possible by changing local governmentby-laws. The change opened up new opportunities <strong>for</strong> poormen and women; <strong>the</strong> ILO is w<strong>ork</strong>ing with local partnerstowards ensuring that <strong>the</strong> jobs are safe and productive.Source: ILO, Success Africa: Partnership <strong>for</strong> Decent W<strong>ork</strong> — ImprovingPeople’s Lives, 2nd vol. (Addis Ababa, Apr. 2007), pp. 2- 4 and31-33.301


e<strong>for</strong>m, as Box 5.3 indicates.Post-conflict states present a special situation<strong>for</strong> legal empowerment even if <strong>the</strong> central statehas nominally reasserted its claim to authority. Itis particularly vexing to figure out how to returnproperty after its rightful owners have fled or beenkilled by one side or <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r in a civil war. Often<strong>the</strong> disputes over homes and o<strong>the</strong>r assets are sointense <strong>the</strong>y must be addressed at once to sustainpeace. 6 The international community has recognisedinstitutional re<strong>for</strong>m of <strong>the</strong> legal infrastructureis essential <strong>for</strong> reconstruction and reconciliation.Yet, a realistic timeframe <strong>for</strong> recreating a justicesystem following serious armed conflict with <strong>for</strong>malcourts, trained judges and a retrained police <strong>for</strong>ceis close to 20 years (Samuels 2006: 19). That is along period <strong>for</strong> implementation with many chances<strong>for</strong> administrative operation to deviate from initialpolicy intent.Merilee Grindle (2007) proposes an elementarytypology of political systems, adapted here in Table5.3, right, which is a useful place to begin to considerwhat sort of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorpolicies are feasible within different countries. Thethree left-hand side column headings reflect <strong>the</strong>political and administrative dimensions of regimes,with <strong>the</strong> far right-hand column very roughly indicating<strong>the</strong> sorts of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor initiativesthat might be appropriate; <strong>the</strong> rows are fivecommon regime patterns or syndromes. These areheuristic, but <strong>the</strong>y suggest <strong>the</strong> possibilities <strong>for</strong> legalempowerment are greatest in states that are morecompetitive and better institutionalised. As Grindlepoints out, <strong>the</strong>re is simply more to build upon in<strong>the</strong>se countries than in weaker states. A startingpoint <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor practitioners,<strong>the</strong>n, is to debate honestly where a particularcountry can be located among <strong>the</strong> common patternsof political administrative systems, and use <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mation to think creatively but realistically aboutwhat empowering re<strong>for</strong>ms will w<strong>ork</strong> in that context.The typology in Table 5.3, right, is educative, notexhaustive; <strong>the</strong> capsule policy prescriptions in <strong>the</strong>last column on <strong>the</strong> right are not meant to cover all<strong>the</strong> possibilities, which are too numerous to capturein a simple table. The reality on <strong>the</strong> ground is thatpolicy champions may need to pursue a variety oftactics in every country, custom fit to <strong>the</strong> differentstakeholders, to support <strong>the</strong>ir overall strategy.That means mobilising <strong>the</strong> grassroots, <strong>the</strong> communityorganisations, <strong>the</strong> professional groups, ando<strong>the</strong>r interests to counterbalance opponents ofLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor trying to derail <strong>the</strong>agenda. The prospect of w<strong>ork</strong>ing with state actorsvaries according to <strong>the</strong> administrative capacity of<strong>the</strong> government.In<strong>for</strong>malityAcross-cutting dimension of <strong>the</strong> policy environmentis <strong>the</strong> extent of in<strong>for</strong>mality — in <strong>the</strong>economy, in <strong>the</strong> polity, and in <strong>the</strong> juridical system.People, organisations, and firms can operate underconditions of in<strong>for</strong>mality <strong>for</strong> some purposes andunder conditions of <strong>for</strong>mality <strong>for</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs. LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>mers must besensitive to <strong>the</strong> vulnerability of in<strong>for</strong>mal empowermentmechanisms to cooptation and domination byelites and <strong>for</strong>mal organisations. Let us look at <strong>the</strong>phenomenon and consider <strong>the</strong> impact on implementationof Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor.In <strong>the</strong> economic sense, in<strong>for</strong>mality refers to smallscale,self-financed and unskilled labour-intensiveproductive activities, which <strong>the</strong> poor use to survive.These pursuits are under-<strong>the</strong>-table and off-<strong>the</strong>books,and thus are legally defenceless againstmore powerful market interests and are subject tounfair exploitation. This parallel or shadow economyis a vast domain, representing <strong>the</strong> equivalentof about 40 percent of official economic activityin developing and transition countries, according302


Table 5.3. Political Administrative SyndromesPoliticalCompetitionInstitutionalstability of <strong>the</strong> stateOrganisationalcapacity of <strong>the</strong> statePotential Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor policyinitiatives*National level re<strong>for</strong>ms inhuman and economic rights;assert claims to existing legaland basic welfare services;w<strong>ork</strong> through established civilsocietyRule through stable andlegitimate organisationsand procedures; opencompetition <strong>for</strong> powerthrough programmematicpartiesRules of <strong>the</strong> game widelyrecognized as legitimateand not subject tosignifi cant change; conflictsresolved through appeal to<strong>the</strong> rulesHigh. Organisationschallenged to improveper<strong>for</strong>mance on a sustainedbasis.Rule through stable andlegitimate organisationsand procedures; no opencompetition <strong>for</strong> power.Political parties serve <strong>the</strong>regime or are hindered andcontrolled by itClear rules of <strong>the</strong> game andgenerally orderly processesof decision-making andpublic management are inplace; generally centralizedand authoritarian practices.Modest. Many organisationscarry out routine activitieson a sustained basis.Mobilisation of poor citizens<strong>for</strong> greater influence over <strong>the</strong>range of legal protections andopportunities from <strong>the</strong> centreAn unstable mixture ofpersonal and impersonalrule, with varying degreesof legitimacy. Partiesare based partly onpersonalitiesRule through personalitiesand personal connections.If political partiesexist, <strong>the</strong>y are based onpersonalities.Basic rules of <strong>the</strong> gameare established in lawand practice, although<strong>the</strong>y function poorly andintermittently.Low. There may be someorganisations that are ableto carry out responsibilitieson a sustained basis.Similar to above, but withpossibly more decentralisedfocus and more emphasis oninstitution building; corruptbureaucracy may be a biggerobstacleBypass strategies to get aroundcorrupt officials; incrementalsteps only; watch out <strong>for</strong> elitecaptureStability highly dependenton personal control ofpower. Rules of <strong>the</strong> gameemphasise power of elitesand personal connections toelites; <strong>the</strong>re is confl ict overwho controls <strong>the</strong> stateLow. Organisations respondto <strong>the</strong> personal and shiftingpriorities of powerful elites.There is no effective centralgovernmentExtremely low. There are noeffective rules of <strong>the</strong> gamethat are agreed uponExtremely low. It is difficultto identify organisationsthat have any capacity toproduce results.Community-basedempowerment programmemes* Illustrative examples only; <strong>the</strong> activities in <strong>the</strong>se cells are not mutually exclusive.to a study financed by <strong>the</strong> World Bank (Schneider2002). Half or more of <strong>the</strong> employment (includingsubsistence farming) in developing countriesis outside <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal sector. Earnings are low anduncertain, but <strong>the</strong>se parallel market activities haveproven remarkably vital and have grown worldwidein new guises and unexpected places. Capturing<strong>the</strong> positive attributes of <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economywhile minimising <strong>the</strong> low productivity and hazardousw<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions that go along with it, isone of <strong>the</strong> challenges of <strong>the</strong> legal empowermentagenda.Economic in<strong>for</strong>mality does have some advantages<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor; <strong>for</strong> example, women may find home-303


ased w<strong>ork</strong> easier to fit in around <strong>the</strong>ir householdresponsibilities. Formal sector businesses maychoose to outsource w<strong>ork</strong> to in<strong>for</strong>mal w<strong>ork</strong>ers togain flexibility. That said, <strong>the</strong>se jobs are mostlyvery badly paid, often dangerous, and <strong>the</strong>y relyheavily on children (ILO 2003). Most people whotoil in <strong>the</strong> parallel economy do so out of necessity,not freely exercised choice. Judith Tendler (2002)writes of an implicit ‘devil’s deal’ in Brazil and o<strong>the</strong>rcountries, whereby in<strong>for</strong>mal economy w<strong>ork</strong>ers andentrepreneurs consent to support certain politicians.In return, <strong>the</strong> politicians agree not to en<strong>for</strong>ce tax,environmental, or labour regulations; and to keep<strong>the</strong> police and inspectors from harassing <strong>the</strong> poor.This arrangement is difficult <strong>for</strong> ei<strong>the</strong>r side to getout of and it limits <strong>the</strong> options <strong>for</strong> legal empowerment.Tendler suggests <strong>the</strong> way to break <strong>the</strong> ‘devil’sdeal’ is by demonstrating <strong>the</strong> paths by which smallfirms grow into <strong>for</strong>m ones, including treating w<strong>ork</strong>ersbetter and helping to upgrade <strong>the</strong>ir skills.The boundary between <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal and <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>maleconomies is fluid and poor people can push it in adirection that favours <strong>the</strong>m. Cairo, to take an example,has an in<strong>for</strong>mal refuse collection system whichactually has a well-defined set of internal rights,responsibilities, and sanctions that evolved overseveral decades in response to a changing externalenvironment. The city tried to bring refuse collectionunder municipal control by issuing licenses to largecorporate contractors. Refuse collection is a majorenterprise <strong>for</strong> poor people so <strong>the</strong> city was threatening<strong>the</strong>ir livelihood. After negotiation and mutualadjustment, a new arrangement emerged in whichsmall-scale service providers selectively adoptedinstitutional <strong>for</strong>ms recognised by <strong>the</strong> municipalauthorities, while hanging on to <strong>the</strong> personalisedand adaptable practices that marked <strong>the</strong>ir in<strong>for</strong>malsystem (Assaad 1996). The second element ofin<strong>for</strong>mality that concerns Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor policy implementation is found in <strong>the</strong> politicalsystem. Similar to what goes on in <strong>the</strong> economy,in<strong>for</strong>mality here is based on implicit and unwrittenunderstandings. In effect, it is a coping method <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor. The terms used to describe this grey governmentzone are ‘patrimonialism’ and ‘clientelism.’Its dimensions are hard to measure, but <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>malpatron-client political system is widespread inmany countries and may crowd out <strong>the</strong> official statesystem of rule, along with that system’s broad policiesthat guarantee rights and distribute privilegesaccording to objective criteria.Patron-client politics emerge from webs ofpersonal bonds that develop between patronsand <strong>the</strong>ir individual clients or followers. Thesebonds are founded on mutual material advantage:<strong>the</strong> patron furnishes excludable resources (money,jobs) in return <strong>for</strong> support and cooperation (votes,attendance at rallies). Typically, marginalizedmembers of society are drawn into patron-clientarrangements as a more reliable means than<strong>the</strong> state to take care of <strong>the</strong>ir everyday concerns(Brinkerhoff and Goldsmith 2004). Clientelismis widely seen as a barrier to more transparentgovernance and professional public administration.It lives on, however, because it provides somethingof value to people. No society is so ‘advanced’ thatit relies exclusively on de jure institutions to run itscommon affairs. For all <strong>the</strong>ir drawbacks, in<strong>for</strong>malpatron-client exchanges are expedient means to getthings done.Clientelism evolves and adapts to <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>malgovernance system, similar to what happens in <strong>the</strong>economic sphere. In fact, individuals who hold<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal levers of power are often also head uppatronage netw<strong>ork</strong>s. Political openness, widespreadpolitical participation and <strong>the</strong> emergence of broadprogrammeme that help people regardless of <strong>the</strong>irpersonal affiliations are ways ‘clientelism’ can bepushed back to benefit <strong>the</strong> poor (Brinkerhoff andGoldsmith 2005). But this is a struggle. Patrons do304


not give up <strong>the</strong>ir position willingly, and <strong>the</strong>y oftenhave multiple additional claims to power, not just<strong>the</strong>ir control over material resources but also legitimacyderived from a high position in <strong>the</strong> local systemof social stratification and privilege. There maybe a religiously or historically derived convention ofdeference to authority that makes poor people lesslikely to stand up <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir prescribed rights against<strong>the</strong> wishes of traditional patrons.The participatory budget process in Porto Alegre,Brazil illustrates how hardy ‘‘clientelism’’ canbe. The city has garnered a great deal of attention<strong>for</strong> making public spending more programmematicand universal, and less dependent on individualconnections and friends in high places. When <strong>the</strong>W<strong>ork</strong>ers Party came to power in Porto Alegre in1989, it was determined to end <strong>the</strong> ‘clientelism’ of<strong>the</strong> old administration and it set up an inclusive processthat involved citizens from all social groups inestablishing budget priorities, allocating investmentsand monitoring results. Many city council representativesheld office based on clientelistic netw<strong>ork</strong>stied to neighbourhood associations. Though oftendisagreeing with participatory budgeting, <strong>the</strong>y voted<strong>for</strong> it with <strong>the</strong> hope of using <strong>the</strong> programmeme’spopularity to gain votes in <strong>the</strong> next election. It wasdifficult <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>se legislators to oppose projects thatdirectly benefited <strong>the</strong>ir own constituents (Wampler2007). Despite this progress, after <strong>the</strong> W<strong>ork</strong>ersParty lost control of <strong>the</strong> city government in 2004,due in part to a drop in support from its low-incomepolitical base, <strong>the</strong>re were signs of resurgent ‘clientelism’,with <strong>the</strong> city councillors and municipal staffonce again doing deals to arrange individualiseddelivery of public w<strong>ork</strong>s and services.In<strong>for</strong>mality turns up a third time in <strong>the</strong> legalsystem itself, where we again see overlappingstatutory and non-state systems of law (includingmafia-like self-regulating systems) in everycountry. As with economic in<strong>for</strong>mality and political‘clientelism’, <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal legal structures existpartly because <strong>the</strong>y are more accessible and ‘userfriendly’ to people of limited means. Sometimes,private or mixed arrangements <strong>for</strong> rule en<strong>for</strong>cementand settlement are efficient because <strong>the</strong>y enjoy<strong>the</strong> confidence of <strong>the</strong> participants and encourageflexibility and compromise within communitynorms. O<strong>the</strong>r times, however, <strong>the</strong> non-state systemis nei<strong>the</strong>r efficient nor fair.The minibus-taxi industry in South Africa shows how<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economic and governance domainscan coincide in <strong>the</strong> real world, in this instance withmajor social cost. Minibuses are <strong>the</strong> major means oftransportation <strong>for</strong> South Africa’s poor, plus a majorsource of employment <strong>for</strong> poor people. A loophole in<strong>the</strong> transit law allowed this largely unregulated sectorto emerge toward <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> apar<strong>the</strong>id era,and commuter transportation became dominatedby independent small, business operators, drivingowned or rented vehicles. The minibus-taxi businessprovided low-cost movement around <strong>the</strong> country ata time when <strong>the</strong> majority was trying to get out fromunder <strong>the</strong> oppressive minority regime ruling SouthAfrica, and it has continued to grow to currentlyaccount <strong>for</strong> about two-thirds of commuter travel.In <strong>the</strong> absence of government regulation, however,<strong>the</strong> individual minibus owners and drivers turned toemerging private industry associations to allocatetaxi routes and cab stands, and to settle disputesthat arose among competitors. Over time, <strong>the</strong>se associationsgrew very powerful in <strong>the</strong>ir own right andbegan to use strong-arm tactics to defend or expandturf claimed by rival taxi groups. By <strong>the</strong> mid-1990sa virtual taxi war was costing hundred of drivers andpassengers <strong>the</strong>ir lives each year. Lack of vehiclemaintenance, overloading and poor safety standardsled to thousands of additional fatalities per year inroad accidents. According to reports, <strong>the</strong> police havebeen corrupted to look <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r way on traffic violationsand in some cases have become leaders in <strong>the</strong>305


Box 5.4 Organising out ofPoverty: Taxis in RwandaThe International Cooperatives Alliance, <strong>the</strong> InternationalTrade Union Confederation (<strong>for</strong>merly <strong>the</strong>ICFTU) and <strong>the</strong> International Labour Organisationhave teamed up to develop an approach known asSYNDICOOP. ‘SYNDICOOP promotes trade unions andcooperatives — membership-based organisations <strong>for</strong>w<strong>ork</strong>ers in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy. And because <strong>the</strong>yare membership organisations, <strong>the</strong>y can be accountable.’An example is Assetamorwa (Association del’Esperance des Taxis Moto au Rwanda) inRwanda. ‘Each driver is an individual trader, negotiatingfares with passengers. But by combining toge<strong>the</strong>r,<strong>the</strong>y support each o<strong>the</strong>r and can negotiate with <strong>the</strong>authorities of Kigali, <strong>the</strong> Rwandan capital.’ Assetamorwahas organised a system of pooling moneythat its members can tap in turn (known as tontine)and a health insurance fund <strong>for</strong> members. The groupalso trains young drivers, runs a garage and sparepartsdepot, and w<strong>ork</strong>s to combat <strong>the</strong> spread ofHIV/AIDS. All of this activity depends on <strong>the</strong> necessaryframew<strong>ork</strong> legislation on freedom of association andcooperatives being in place at <strong>the</strong> national level.Source: Stirling Smith and Cilla Ross, Organising out of poverty:Stories from <strong>the</strong> grassroots: How <strong>the</strong> SYNDICOOP approach hasw<strong>ork</strong>ed in East Africa (Co-operative College, Oldham, 2006).violence and intimidation among taxi associations(Barrett 2003).Fortunately, freedom of association is guaranteedby law in South Africa, and <strong>the</strong> governmenthas a non-judicial mechanism to resolvedisputes through mediation and conciliation. Thus,institutional and legal conditions exist <strong>for</strong> overcoming<strong>the</strong> industry’s problems. The government hastried to reassert its regulatory authority and <strong>for</strong>malize<strong>the</strong> industry. After consultation with stakeholders,a financial incentive programmeme has beendeveloped to encourage operators to upgrade <strong>the</strong>minibus fleet, join designated membership associations,keep better records and begin payingtaxes on <strong>the</strong>ir enterprises (van der Merwe 2007).The effectiveness of <strong>the</strong>se ef<strong>for</strong>ts to supplant <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal institutions and practices remains to beproven, however.This example is extreme, and Box 5.4 reports amuch more encouraging case of a taxi drivers’organisation from Africa; never<strong>the</strong>less, it makes <strong>the</strong>point that development practitioners face dilemmasin dealing with in<strong>for</strong>mality (and, by extension,with decentralised and local institutions generally).There are obvious advantages to exercising rightsthrough personalized and traditional authority becauseit is less expensive, more familiar and locallyavailable. Yet, just because de facto or relationship-basedauthority is embedded in poor communitiesdoes not mean <strong>the</strong>y must be constructivein fighting poverty and injustice, as <strong>the</strong> violentfeuding of <strong>the</strong> South African taxi case vividly illustrates.A patron-client netw<strong>ork</strong>, or clique, mayprovide a safe haven <strong>for</strong> society’s most vulnerable,but it limits <strong>the</strong>ir options also, long-establishedrules <strong>for</strong> allocating resources may w<strong>ork</strong> when <strong>the</strong>population is small, but <strong>the</strong>y might buckle underpopulation pressure. Additionally, a private legalmechanism may be accessible, but it could easilyplay favourites depending on a plaintiff’s personalconnections.A bottom-line concern is that development professionalsmust creatively seek to capitalise on <strong>the</strong>available mix of de facto or ‘traditional’ modes ofauthority. There is no reason to assume that <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal institutions, rules and arrangements areei<strong>the</strong>r superior or inferior to <strong>the</strong>ir de jure or ‘modern’counterparts. Context is critical. India is a possiblemodel <strong>for</strong> how to integrate representative andlegal institutions, having extended official recognitionto a system of village councils and people’s306


Box 5.5 Authority Systems: Land RightsRegarding <strong>the</strong> critical asset of land, <strong>the</strong>re exists aninternationally well recognized spectrum of rights, asshown in <strong>the</strong> figure below. Starting with <strong>the</strong> floor offreedom from eviction, security of tenure progressivelyimproves as one follows <strong>the</strong> arrow. Land rights begin with<strong>the</strong> perception that one will not be evicted, based oftenon political statements to that effect. The right becomesstronger through customary law, temporary occupancycertifi cates, through anti-eviction legislation and adversepossession (o<strong>the</strong>rwise known as squatters’ rights) andgroup tenure. Long-term leases and individual freeholdtenure represent <strong>the</strong> most secure <strong>for</strong>ms of tenure. Thenoteworthy feature of <strong>the</strong> continuum of land rights isthat it accommodates and reflects <strong>the</strong> diverse realityof land rights and social land tenures that exist in <strong>the</strong>world today (<strong>for</strong> example, family and group rights). It alsodemonstrates <strong>the</strong> potential <strong>for</strong> an incremental path togreater security consistent with <strong>the</strong> way <strong>the</strong> poor accumulate<strong>the</strong>ir resources over time. This approach may be asolid foundation <strong>for</strong> achieving consensus on <strong>the</strong> issue ofland and property rights. It is also a good starting point<strong>for</strong> developing an innovative spectrum of protection andopportunities in this area, where parallel opportunitiesprotection/securityspectrums can also be linked (e.g.labour, justice, entrepreneurship).Continuum of RightsLegal or<strong>for</strong>mal rightsCustomaryPerceived tenure approaches:• Political statements• Services without legal tenureAnti evictionsOccupancyLeasesGroup tenureAdverse possessionRegisteredfreeholdIllegal orin<strong>for</strong>mal rightscourts. Drawing on traditional norms, <strong>the</strong> councilsare reported to be seeking out new roles and tobe adapting to <strong>the</strong> democratic factor in India’s<strong>for</strong>mal political institutions (Pur and Moore 2007).Several West African countries use decentralisedlocal councils to administer land laws. Thesetend to be based on customary power structures,though as yet <strong>the</strong>y appear upwardly accountable to<strong>the</strong> central state, ra<strong>the</strong>r than downwardly to localpopulations (Ribot 1999). Box 5.5 discusses how<strong>the</strong> integration of <strong>for</strong>mality and in<strong>for</strong>mality mayhelp <strong>the</strong> poor with land rights generally.In all instances poor people’s perceptions shouldbe kept front and centre. Legal or organisationalre<strong>for</strong>ms that look self-evidently empowering toexperts from outside <strong>the</strong> poor community may lookdangerous from <strong>the</strong> perspective of someone on <strong>the</strong>inside. This could detract from <strong>the</strong> local supportneeded <strong>for</strong> implementation.’As we finish this aspect of Section 2, it should bemore than evident how important contextual analysisis to implementation of Legal Empowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>ms. Policy makers have to come togrips with <strong>the</strong> national environment of public policy— that is, with <strong>the</strong> domestic social structure, economiccontext, nature of <strong>the</strong> political and administrativesystems, and <strong>the</strong> scale of economic andlegal in<strong>for</strong>mality. While a country’s environment <strong>for</strong>re<strong>for</strong>m has to be unpacked and probed on its ownterms, we have offered useful questions that couldbe asked. Practitioners and policymakers can makegood use of <strong>the</strong> tool of contextual analysis to determineif conditions appear ripe <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>ms, which implementationscenarios seem most probable, what sequencingand timelines <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m look doable and how <strong>the</strong>y307


should be designed, what tradeoffs need to beconsidered, which risk mitigating mechanisms areworth trying, and what contextual variables needcareful monitoring during implementation. Adheringto this general set of guidelines will increase<strong>the</strong> chances of successfully carrying out empowermentpolicies.Policy characteristicsThree internal policy characteristics (<strong>the</strong> lowermiddle box in Figure 5.2, above) stand out ininfluencing implementation: complexity, ambiguityand <strong>the</strong> potential <strong>for</strong> discord and conflict. Thesecharacteristics are important in all policy arenas butare especially relevant <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> four domains of legalempowerment.ComplexityO<strong>the</strong>r things being equal, <strong>the</strong> more complex a policyis, <strong>the</strong> harder it is to implement due to <strong>the</strong> intensityof <strong>the</strong> administrative ef<strong>for</strong>t required. On <strong>the</strong> scale ofcomplexity, Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor tendsto fall at <strong>the</strong> far end. As seen by <strong>the</strong> Commission,<strong>the</strong> paradigm <strong>for</strong> empowerment is holistic and thushighly ambitious. Ideally, <strong>the</strong> poor should obtainlegal protection <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir physical and financialassets (property rights) and human capital (labourrights), and also have <strong>the</strong> ability to engage in markettransactions (business rights). Cutting across allthree areas is a need to obtain access to justiceand political decision making (legal identity andcitizenship rights). Those are a lot of balls to juggleduring implementation. It may be best to go <strong>for</strong>wardselectively and not dissipate energy on too many initiativesat once. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, progress in onlyone area without <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs may create imbalancesthat perpetuate poverty.A second source of complexity is <strong>the</strong> fact that legaland regulatory systems are very robust; meaningthat reconfiguration of one or a few aspects of <strong>the</strong>law or institutions may not alter <strong>the</strong> overall risk andlack of opportunity poor people face. Social conventionsand structures develop over long periodswith many redundancies and mutually rein<strong>for</strong>cingelements. Progress in one domain of empowermentmay be neutralised by lack of progress in ano<strong>the</strong>r.Unanticipated effects may also be triggered duringimplementation that undermine or bypass <strong>the</strong>intended beneficiaries. In Peru, <strong>for</strong> instance, <strong>the</strong> introductionof greater flexibility in <strong>the</strong> labour marketwas heralded as progress in <strong>the</strong> early to mid 1990s;one of its effects, however, was to drastically reduce<strong>the</strong> percentage of <strong>the</strong> population who enjoyed alegal status as employees, which had given <strong>the</strong>maccess to social protection. Poverty rates increasedin <strong>the</strong> short-term. Had <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m package beenless sweeping, or accompanied by a social floor ormitigating measures, this negative impact mighthave been avoided.Third is <strong>the</strong> time dimension to complexity. Empowermentpolicies seldom take effect quickly. Regardinglaw re<strong>for</strong>m to promote <strong>the</strong> right to freedom ofassociation and collective bargaining, <strong>for</strong> instance,<strong>the</strong> ILO (2004: 110-111) has observed that fourto five years is <strong>the</strong> minimum time that should beallowed be<strong>for</strong>e substantive results can be seen. Ingeneral, delays make political back-tracking likely asministerial appointments change and bring in newministers who have little interest or commitmentto <strong>the</strong>ir predecessor’s programmemes. Hesitationin implementation rein<strong>for</strong>ces any inclination of <strong>the</strong>poor not to go along as expected with a policy in <strong>the</strong>first place. Individual uncertainty about implementationencourages <strong>the</strong> majority to hold back supporting<strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m, which creates a self-fulfilling prophecyof implementation slippage. Thus it is importantto look <strong>for</strong> interventions that promise short-termrewards <strong>for</strong> beneficiaries. Micro-finance, <strong>for</strong> example,can have an immediate (though perhaps notsustainable) effect on poor people’s consumption.308


Afinal source of complexity is that legal empowermentis both a top-down activity (initiativeand coordination often come from <strong>the</strong> nationalcapital, regional centre, or city hall) and a bottomupactivity (<strong>the</strong> poor and <strong>the</strong>ir allies play a centralrole as advocates and watchdogs). There are manychances <strong>for</strong> misunderstanding and miscommunicationwith a policy where leadership comes fromseveral directions. Even if NGOs and local communitiesare <strong>the</strong> prime movers of Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor, <strong>the</strong>y may not be able to accomplishmuch on <strong>the</strong>ir own without government assistance.An example of how complexity can distort implementationof Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor is<strong>the</strong> ongoing struggle over labour rights in LatinAmerica. During <strong>the</strong> 1990s, several governmentsin <strong>the</strong> region tried to promote greater flexibilityin <strong>the</strong> labour market through changes in nationallabour legislation. This undermined labour unionmembers’ freedom of association and rights tocollective bargaining; it also impinged on w<strong>ork</strong>ersas individuals because <strong>the</strong>y lost job security. Tradeunions fought back against <strong>the</strong>se changes and, insome cases, succeeded in curbing erosion of <strong>the</strong>irgroup rights, a positive accomplishment from <strong>the</strong>perspective of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. But<strong>the</strong>y often ceded on deregulation of employmentlaw relating to individual rights, which is perhapsan even greater loss <strong>for</strong> an Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor agenda. An unintended by product of<strong>the</strong>se policy disputes was also to streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>larger and more established unions but to fur<strong>the</strong>rweaken <strong>the</strong> organising and bargaining rights ofemerging rival unions (Cook 2005). These last areoften strong allies of poor people.AmbiguityAmbiguous policies are also more challenging tocarry out than clear policies are. There are severalreasons <strong>for</strong> this, but a principal one is that ambiguitygives bureaucratic stakeholders greater discretionin interpreting or even ignoring <strong>the</strong> policy.Ambiguity also clouds <strong>the</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>ts of beneficiariesand sponsor groups to hold <strong>the</strong> bureaucrats toaccount. As a result, <strong>the</strong> policy in practice tendsto drift fur<strong>the</strong>r and fur<strong>the</strong>r away from its design.Many policies related to Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor rank relatively high <strong>for</strong> ambiguity. In severalAfrican countries, <strong>for</strong> example, local people’s accessto land is protected through use rights, whichare legally recognised as long as <strong>the</strong> land is put toproductive use. What uses are ‘productive’ is notclear in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal law, however, which tends tofavour large-scale commercial or industrial usersnot pastoralist or subsistence farmers seeking accessto land (Cotula 2007: 36). The less clear-cuta policy is, generally <strong>the</strong> greater is <strong>the</strong> probabilityof elite capture during implementation.The in<strong>for</strong>mal legal arrangements discussed earlierare a source of ambiguity simply because <strong>the</strong>y existside by side with <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal system of civil andcriminal justice. Which one takes precedence? Theinadvertent result could be a labyrinth of law, inwhich <strong>the</strong> poor and disadvantaged may lose <strong>the</strong>irway. Setting aside any possible net advantages ofin<strong>for</strong>mality <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor in a given legal context, <strong>the</strong>absence of documentation tends to render in<strong>for</strong>maljustice a less effective plat<strong>for</strong>m <strong>for</strong> implementingempowerment strategies. Consider <strong>the</strong> phenomenonknown as ‘<strong>for</strong>um shopping’ whereby economicactors navigate among multiple legal orders to seek<strong>the</strong> most favourable <strong>for</strong>um to pursue <strong>the</strong>ir claims.Thus a policy to give legal recognition to poorpeople’s customary system of justice or disputeresolution may in some cases w<strong>ork</strong> against <strong>the</strong>poor, as long as <strong>the</strong> statutory or rule-based legalcode continues to exist. A business corporation orrich person will simply avoid <strong>the</strong> less expensivetraditional <strong>for</strong>um and <strong>for</strong>ce poor people to litigatein <strong>for</strong>ums where <strong>the</strong>y are at a disadvantage. The309


flip side of <strong>for</strong>um shopping is that NGOs and humanrights stakeholder groups w<strong>ork</strong>ing on behalf of<strong>the</strong> poor also have multiple venues to seek redressof <strong>the</strong>ir grievances, so, again, <strong>the</strong> implication isnot that institutional pluralism is inherently bad <strong>for</strong>Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. Still, it is a complicatingfactor that makes empowerment policiestrickier to plan and execute.There may be temptation to clarify anambiguous in<strong>for</strong>mal legal structure simplyby replacing it with a more orderly statutory code,but as it might conceivably backfire on <strong>the</strong> poor,any approach must be carefully reasoned. Sudanis an acute case of what can happen when changeis suddenly rushed though. Urban elites in Sudanaggressively moved to take land at less than itstrue value by shifting land out of community-basedtenure systems and into a standardised Islamictenure system. The civil war that raged <strong>for</strong> years in<strong>the</strong> south of <strong>the</strong> country was set in motion <strong>for</strong> manyreasons, but one was <strong>the</strong> resistance by rural peopleto <strong>the</strong> imposition of an unfamiliar tenure systemthat destroyed <strong>the</strong>ir traditional land rights (Bruceet al. 1998: 195). The conflict in Sudan’s Darfurregion also grows in part out of conflicts aroundcompeting systems of land tenure, representedby group-based camel nomadism, on <strong>the</strong> onehand, and more individually oriented sedentarycultivation, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r (Abdul-Jalil 2005).Ambiguity additionally clouds lines of accountabilityand responsibility among implementing agenciesand allows <strong>the</strong>m to ‘pass <strong>the</strong> buck’ during implementation.In post-tsunami Sri Lanka, <strong>the</strong> housingauthority allocated land to <strong>the</strong> displaced which waslater found to have been under claim by <strong>the</strong> municipalityas a waste dump, and had been classifiedby <strong>the</strong> water board as uninhabitable. Straighteningout mix-ups like this takes time and energy thatcould have been used more productively.DiscordThe distributional strife unear<strong>the</strong>d by policy ambiguityin countries such as Sudan merges into <strong>the</strong>third stylised internal influence on implementation,which is a policy’s inbuilt potential to generatedissension. An ‘iron law of public policy’ saysthat most acts of government, no matter what <strong>the</strong>broader merits, create winners and losers. If <strong>the</strong>gains and losses are seen as significant, <strong>the</strong>y willbecome <strong>the</strong> object of intense political attention.This is particularly likely where <strong>the</strong> policy redistributesa right or benefit from one group to ano<strong>the</strong>r,as happens when <strong>the</strong>re are mutually exclusiveclaims to a fixed resource such as fertile land orminerals. Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor attemptsto minimise redistributive conflicts by expandingeconomic opportunities so that different interestscan be negotiated to meet every side’s needs, but<strong>the</strong>re is still plenty of potential <strong>for</strong> confrontationbecause important stakeholders believe o<strong>the</strong>rs’gains come at <strong>the</strong>ir expense. The mutual payoff tolegal empowerment is in <strong>the</strong> future, but <strong>the</strong> individualsacrifices must be borne now.A concrete example of this ‘iron law’ is <strong>the</strong> titlingand registration programmeme implemented in Perustarting in <strong>the</strong> 1980s. According to a World Bankreport, <strong>the</strong> main winners were: settlers, who accrued<strong>the</strong> economic and social benefits of <strong>for</strong>mal ownership;<strong>the</strong> President of Peru, who earned <strong>the</strong> politicalcredit <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> programmeme; local mayors, whoshared <strong>the</strong> political credit, and congressmen, whobacked <strong>the</strong> legal framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>malization. Theprincipal losers were reportedly <strong>the</strong> public officialsin charge of regularisation processes who previouslybenefited from bribes; lawyers and notaries, who lost<strong>the</strong> monopoly <strong>the</strong>y enjoyed in <strong>the</strong> traditional registrationsystem, and <strong>for</strong>mer community leaders, whowere replaced by new leaders elected by <strong>the</strong> communitiesduring <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms (Palacio 2006: 41).In conflict equations, defenders of <strong>the</strong> status quo310


almost always have <strong>the</strong> upper hand because <strong>the</strong>yhave won earlier power struggles over <strong>the</strong> samepublic policies. With Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor a special difficulty is that <strong>the</strong> self-perceived‘losers’ are apt to include members of <strong>the</strong> local eliteand bureaucrats mentioned earlier, who feel <strong>the</strong>irmonopoly on neighbourhood or community power isjeopardised should anyone else gain economic andfinancial independence. While <strong>the</strong>se stakeholdershave many means to delay or dilute implementationof policies <strong>the</strong>y reject — especially by co-opting <strong>the</strong>poor through <strong>the</strong> dependency relationships of patronageand ‘clientelism’ and by corrupting <strong>the</strong> localbureaucracy — <strong>the</strong> example of Peru proves it is possibleto overcome <strong>the</strong> odds with <strong>the</strong> right leadershipand a winning coalition of support.Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor conflicts canbe mapped and considered be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong>y come toa head, providing time to think about politicalstrategies to manage <strong>the</strong> tension. A policy’s costand benefit can both be widely distributed (spreadover most citizens) or narrowly focused (limited toan identifiable group). Decisions by a central bankto greatly expand <strong>the</strong> money supply, <strong>for</strong> instance,have widely distributed costs because everyonehas to pay <strong>the</strong> consequent inflated prices <strong>for</strong> goodsand services. Regulations targeting a specificindustry, such as licensing or safety inspections<strong>for</strong> minicab taxis (mentioned earlier), are morefocused and narrowly concentrated and may beperceived as a loss or gain <strong>for</strong> those most affected.In o<strong>the</strong>r words, whe<strong>the</strong>r people see <strong>the</strong>mselves aspolicy winners or losers is more important than <strong>the</strong>reality of who wins or loses. By and large, we cangroup <strong>the</strong> varieties of political situations into fourcategories; <strong>the</strong>y are shown in Figure 5.3. 7 Each hasdifferent implications <strong>for</strong> generating conflict.Figure 5.3 Conflict Implications of Public PolicyPerceived policy costdispersed concentratedPerceived policy benefitnarrowWinner takes all(high conflict due tozero-sumcompetition)Patron-clientpolitics/corruption(stable, low conflictbecause costs arehidden andbeneficiaries havelittle inducement tochange)wideCollective Inaction(little incentive <strong>for</strong>beneficiaries tomobilize; strongincentives <strong>for</strong>victims to react) –Need policyentrepreneursConsensus politics(low conflict due toapparent positive –sum gains)Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor policies such asland titling or legal assistance fall in <strong>the</strong> top twocells in this matrix. Where both cost and benefitare narrowly concentrated (<strong>the</strong> top left cell),each side has an incentive to dig in to defend itsinterests by preventing or establishing <strong>the</strong> transferof resources. Because <strong>the</strong> policy affects relativelyfew people, gaining allies may be difficult <strong>for</strong> bothsides unless <strong>the</strong>y can make ‘side payments’ orengage in ‘logrolling’. 8 Where <strong>the</strong> benefit is widelydispersed, as might be true of many policies designedto help <strong>the</strong> poor by expanding <strong>the</strong>ir rights,getting those beneficiaries motivated to push <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> policy is difficult because <strong>the</strong> individual gainsare small or may seem abstract. In short, eachcategory of policies tends to have a distinct shapethat Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor practitionersought to be alert to, as <strong>the</strong>y try to predict and influencestakeholder actions. The categories, however,are not air-tight and can metamorphose into oneano<strong>the</strong>r over time, as perceptions of issues change.Thus education and marketing are importantaspects of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor implementationto try to get stakeholders to take a widerperspective on <strong>the</strong>ir self-interest.311


Lessons may be drawn from knowledge about <strong>the</strong>inbuilt characteristics of public policy. For example,as Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor tendsto be complex and ambiguous, and as implementationef<strong>for</strong>ts might <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e be hindered, <strong>the</strong>policies to promote empowerment must be madeas clear-cut and straight<strong>for</strong>ward as possible. Designsimplicity is one way to avoid or minimise conflict,uncertainty and o<strong>the</strong>r implementation problemsarising from procedural and technical traits of legalempowerment activities.Diagnosing <strong>the</strong> Influence on PolicyImplementationWe have emphasised <strong>the</strong> stresses and strains onLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor implementationto awaken policymakers to <strong>the</strong> need to think pragmaticallyand opportunistically about policy re<strong>for</strong>m.Policymaking is not an assembly line, and a <strong>for</strong>mulaicapproach to <strong>the</strong> ‘who’, ‘what’ and ‘where’ factorscould lead to overly pessimistic generalisations andmissed opportunities. Effective implementationrequires a mix of experience, professional judgment,and a willingness to take chances. Creativeactors look <strong>for</strong> policy windows that open up andcreate space <strong>for</strong> moving <strong>for</strong>ward to solve a particularproblem, even when <strong>the</strong> circumstances appear to bedifficult.With <strong>the</strong>se caveats in mind, Table 5.4 outlineshow to catalogue <strong>the</strong> influential factors in differentnations and assess tendencies to impel orimpede implementation (as indicated by <strong>the</strong> threeright-hand columns). The questions are illustrativeand need to be altered to suit different needs andsituations.An approach to implementation <strong>for</strong>Country ‘X’Broadly, Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor implementationin country ‘X’ might start with an environmentalscan and contextual analysis. The focuswould be on 1) social and cultural features thataffect implementation; 2) <strong>the</strong> economic context,which also can be both a help and a hindrance,and 3) on <strong>the</strong> openness and capacity of <strong>the</strong> state.Supplementing <strong>the</strong> inventory of <strong>the</strong>se concernswould be a careful analysis of <strong>the</strong> reach and holdthat in<strong>for</strong>mal institutions have on <strong>the</strong> poor. Thefull contextual analysis would <strong>the</strong>n <strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> basis<strong>for</strong> a feasibility review of various empowermentscenarios.Next (or perhaps simultaneously because <strong>the</strong>se arenever discrete implementation steps), local activistsand external change agents in country ‘X’ would undertakea stakeholder analysis of <strong>the</strong> constituenciesconcerned with Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor.The objective: to differentiate among <strong>the</strong> superficiallyhomogeneous beneficiaries, to better understand<strong>the</strong> divisions, alliances and particular needsthat exist among <strong>the</strong> poor. O<strong>the</strong>r stakeholders, whomight oppose or assist <strong>the</strong> target group or groups,would also be scrutinised to see what motivates<strong>the</strong>ir behaviour and reflect on how <strong>the</strong>y could bebrought into <strong>the</strong> process. The purpose of <strong>the</strong> stakeholderanalysis would be to get a firmer grasp of<strong>the</strong> probability of moving <strong>for</strong>ward with various LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor scenarios, and to beginserious thinking about what it might take to build aminimum winning coalition <strong>for</strong> legal empowermentin country ‘X’.Finally, with possible overlapping chronology, <strong>the</strong>internal technical features of <strong>the</strong> alternative policyscenarios would be reviewed. The policy characteristicsanalysis would focus on <strong>the</strong> complexitiesof <strong>the</strong> various policies, potential ambiguities thatmight possibly sow discord — all of which wouldserve to hinder implementation. Ef<strong>for</strong>ts would bemade to find a simple, incremental and sustainablecourse of action, and to avoid as much as possibletaking steps that provoke confrontation needlessly312


Table 5.4 Skeleton Diagnostic Tool:Analysing Influences on Policy ImplementationQuestions (list is not comprehensive)Effect on ImplementationNegative Positive NeutralPolicy EnvironmentHow extensive are poverty and lack of ownership of or access to productive assets?What is <strong>the</strong> position of women in society?What is <strong>the</strong> degree of social and ethnic heterogeneity? Are <strong>the</strong>re marginalizedminorities?What is <strong>the</strong> relative balance of power among social/ethnic groups?What dependency relations exist between elites and <strong>the</strong> poor?How open and competitive is <strong>the</strong> political system? Nationally? Locally?Is freedom of association guaranteed?To what extent do public agencies operate as effective bureaucracies? Is bureaucraticcorruption common?What is <strong>the</strong> capacity of institutions of <strong>the</strong> state to deal with <strong>the</strong> agenda of legalempowerment? Are accountabilities clearly spelled out?How scarce or abundant are government resources?Anything special about <strong>the</strong> country context? (Transition economy, least developedcountry, post-confl ict, etc.)Policy StakeholdersWho are <strong>the</strong> target benefi ciaries? How many are <strong>the</strong>re? Are <strong>the</strong>y members of an ethnicgroup or groups? Mostly women?Are <strong>the</strong> beneficiaries organised?What civil society organisations exist? Where do <strong>the</strong>y stand on <strong>the</strong> pro-poor policyissue?Who is in opposition to <strong>the</strong> policy? What are <strong>the</strong>ir resources?What allies and potential allies are <strong>the</strong>re <strong>for</strong> empowering <strong>the</strong> poor?Policy CharacteristicsHow complex are <strong>the</strong> changes that are supposed to happen? Are <strong>the</strong>se small departuresfrom current practices or major changes?Is <strong>the</strong> policy geographically concentrated?Does it require a high degree of technical or professional knowledge?What is <strong>the</strong> level of confl ict about <strong>the</strong> value and nature of <strong>the</strong> changes?What does <strong>the</strong> pro-poor policy do? Is this clear or vague?What is <strong>the</strong> desired impact of policy re<strong>for</strong>m, what is it expected to accomplish orfacilitate?313


Table 5.4 Skeleton Diagnostic Tool:Analysing Influences on Policy Implementation cont.Questions (list is not comprehensive)Effect on ImplementationNegative Positive NeutralPolicy Characteristics cont.Where did <strong>the</strong> impetus <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> policy come from?Who decided to pursue <strong>the</strong> policy, how, and why?What is <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong> policy benefi ts, and to whom do <strong>the</strong>y accrue (disaggregated bysex, age and ethnicity)?What is <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong> costs of <strong>the</strong> policy re<strong>for</strong>m, and who bears <strong>the</strong>m(disaggregated by sex, age and ethnicity)?What is <strong>the</strong> degree and complexity of <strong>the</strong> changes brought about by <strong>the</strong> new policy?How administratively intense or technically complex is <strong>the</strong> new policy?— recognising that some confrontation is unavoidableand that it might even prove productive inmoving <strong>the</strong> empowerment agenda <strong>for</strong>ward. Obviously,what <strong>for</strong> w<strong>ork</strong>s <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor in country ‘X’ may be irrelevant in country‘Y’ with a very different social structure, economicenvironment and universe of stakeholder groups.The procedures in determining a suitable LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor strategy might look alikein <strong>the</strong>se two locations, but <strong>the</strong> substance of <strong>the</strong>outcome would be sharply different. And in allcases, <strong>the</strong> process is messy and imprecise, yieldingonly what would appear to be <strong>the</strong> best fitting policiesgiven <strong>the</strong> imperfect in<strong>for</strong>mation available topolicymakers at <strong>the</strong> time and <strong>the</strong> current politicalrealities.impediments to Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorimplementation. That is <strong>the</strong> subject of Section 3.Without looking beyond <strong>the</strong> generic influence onimplementation to any specific cases, we can seethat <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment movement has takenon a stiff but not infeasible implementation challenge.We have placed much stress on <strong>the</strong> need<strong>for</strong> imaginative and adaptable policymaking, butto help imagination along it is imperative to havea number of rough roadmaps that will help totake policymakers around some of <strong>the</strong> pitfalls and314


3.Roadmaps toImplementationRe<strong>for</strong>ms to legally empower <strong>the</strong> poor are multi-faceted.Besides technical analysis and prescription,successful implementation of re<strong>for</strong>ms calls <strong>for</strong>consensus building, participation of key stakeholders,compromise, contingency planning, adaptation,and flexibility. These are <strong>the</strong> ‘how’ or methodissues of implementation. Re<strong>for</strong>ms never proceedin a straight line; change is multi-directional andcalls <strong>for</strong> actions — by donors, government, NGOs,<strong>the</strong> private sector, and communities — sometimesiteratively, sometimes simultaneously, and sometimessequentially. To guide and track <strong>the</strong> necessaryactions to achieve re<strong>for</strong>m ends, a roadmap isuseful to identify and to incorporate <strong>the</strong> technical,institutional, and political and dimensions of <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>m process.In developing an implementation roadmap <strong>for</strong>re<strong>for</strong>ms <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor, ourw<strong>ork</strong>ing group adapted a practical template developedby Brinkerhoff and Crosby (2002), whichdraws on policy re<strong>for</strong>m research from multiplesectors. This template builds on empirical analysisthat identifies a common set of tasks associatedwith successful re<strong>for</strong>m design and implementation.These tasks follow a generalised (but notlockstep) pattern, which can be conceived of as aninteractive cycle comprising <strong>the</strong> following phases:policy <strong>for</strong>mulation and legitimisation, constituencybuilding, resource mobilisation, implementationdesign and organisational development, and actionplanning and progress monitoring. A stream of issues,agendas and decisions launch <strong>the</strong> cycle and,over time, provide additional input and momentumto <strong>the</strong> process.Figure 5.4, adapted from Brinkerhoff and Crosby(2002), illustrates this iterative process of policyimplementation, showing junctures or ‘crossroads’Figure 5.4Roadmap to <strong>the</strong> Implementation CycleAction Planning& ProgressMonitoringImplementationDesign &OrganizationalDeelopmentIssuesAgendasDecisionsPolicy FormulationandLegitimizationConstituencyBuildingResourceMobilizationprimary linkagesecondarywhere choices must be made while moving <strong>the</strong>policy onward. Below is a brief description of tasksassociated with each decision point on <strong>the</strong> roadmap.Issues, Agendas, and Decisions: Advocating <strong>for</strong>change, developing policy issues, lists of items tobe considered, and making decisions that launchLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>ms are <strong>the</strong>precursors to crafting <strong>the</strong> operational content of aspecific policy. For <strong>the</strong>se activities, it is politiciansand interest groups that tend to take <strong>the</strong> lead but<strong>the</strong>y will seldom succeed without pressure frombelow and mobilisation and demands from <strong>the</strong>poor <strong>the</strong>mselves. Out of this process, in <strong>the</strong> ideal,a policy champion will emerge (this could be aninfluential individual, a change team, or a coalition315


of interests). Without <strong>the</strong> commitment to re<strong>for</strong>mand <strong>the</strong> political will to empower <strong>the</strong> poor, it isdifficult, if not impossible, to move to implementation.Commitment and political will depend uponincentives; thus Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorre<strong>for</strong>ms must identify and create reasons <strong>for</strong> governmentand o<strong>the</strong>r entrenched interests to back (orat least not vigorously oppose) <strong>the</strong> pro-poor policy.Policy Formulation and Legitimisation: Address <strong>the</strong>technical content of re<strong>for</strong>m measures. However, besidestechnical content, re<strong>for</strong>m measures need tobe accepted and seen as necessary and important.The poor should, through <strong>the</strong>ir representatives, bepart and parcel of <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m design process.Constituency Building: Convince beneficiaries of<strong>the</strong> advantages of re<strong>for</strong>ms, and demonstrate thatlong-term benefits are worth short-term costs.Resource Mobilisation: Ensure flow of adequateresources by addressing incentives, and exercisingleadership in galvanizing constituencies. Therecommendations of <strong>the</strong> Commission call uponcountries to undertake re<strong>for</strong>ms that will requirefinancial, technical, and human resource commitments.Implementation Design and Organisational Development:Re<strong>for</strong>mers need to create and nurturenetw<strong>ork</strong>s and partnerships <strong>for</strong> cooperation and coordination,and provide <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> development of neworganisational skills and capacities in <strong>the</strong> public,private and non-governmental sectors. Old procedures,operating routines, and communicationpatterns die hard; change is likely to be resistedwithin some quarters.Action Planning and Progress Monitoring: Set upsystems and procedures <strong>for</strong> obtaining feedbackso that implementation is related to learning andadaptation, so as to produce results and impact.Table 5.5 suggests <strong>the</strong> questions to consider indrawing up a roadmap <strong>for</strong> implementing LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor in a specific country— recognising that it is never possible to a havea complete understanding of <strong>the</strong> social structure,political framew<strong>ork</strong> and legal system be<strong>for</strong>ehand,and that even if such <strong>for</strong>eknowledge were possible,it would soon be outdated because <strong>the</strong> factors<strong>the</strong>mselves are constantly changing.Mapping <strong>the</strong> Empowerment DomainsLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor may be perceivedas a spectrum that provides opportunities, protectionand security. It establishes a minimum ‘floor’of entitlements and safeguards to which everyoneis entitled, by <strong>the</strong> simple fact of our commonhumanity. Under each of <strong>the</strong> Commission’s fourcore <strong>the</strong>mes (access to justice, security of assets,labour protection, and entrepreneurial rights), <strong>the</strong>task is to establish this floor using human rightslaw. For every empowerment domain, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e,one challenge is to identify a range of potentialpolicy options from which nations and citizens canchoose, depending on <strong>the</strong>ir national context and<strong>the</strong> different starting points of various groups of<strong>the</strong> poor within <strong>the</strong>m. Finally, and perhaps mostsignificantly, a spectrum approach explicitly recognises<strong>the</strong> incremental manner in which poor peopleimprove <strong>the</strong>ir lives in practice. At each stage of thisimprovement, fundamental rights and an appropriatecombination of protection measures/securityand opportunities must be available to <strong>the</strong>m.It would be futile to propose implementation recommendations<strong>for</strong> universal application; but it ispossible to put <strong>for</strong>ward stylised recommendationsin <strong>the</strong> four domains of empowerment. Table 5.6shows how access to justice issues can be mappedwith protection/opportunity available in variouslegal instruments and with <strong>the</strong> goals of empowerment.316


Table 5.5 Country Specific Implementation Roadmap: RepresentativeSummary ChecklistRe<strong>for</strong>m implementation‘crossroad’Issues, agendas anddecisionsPolicy <strong>for</strong>mulation— legitimisationConstituency buildingResource mobilisationImplementationdesign andorganisationaldevelopmentAction planning andprogress monitoringQuestions to bear in mindContextual analysis and checklist: Are <strong>the</strong> conditions right <strong>for</strong> a legal empowerment re<strong>for</strong>m to succeed?Consultative process: Are <strong>the</strong> poor organised and represented by community groups, NGOs or memberbasedorganisations of w<strong>ork</strong>ers?Have specifi c pro-poor policies been <strong>for</strong>mulated?What Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor policies are proposed/underway?What are <strong>the</strong> characteristics of <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor policies?What does <strong>the</strong> policy do?What is <strong>the</strong> desired impact of policy re<strong>for</strong>m, what is it expected to accomplish or facilitate?Where did <strong>the</strong> impetus <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> policy come from?Who decided to pursue <strong>the</strong> policy, how, and why?What are <strong>the</strong> policy benefits and costs, and who is affected?What is <strong>the</strong> degree and complexity of <strong>the</strong> changes brought about by <strong>the</strong> new policy?What is <strong>the</strong> duration of <strong>the</strong> policy change process?What institutions are involved in implementing <strong>the</strong> policy?How administratively intense or technically complex is <strong>the</strong> new policy?Have Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>m champions been identified, and who are <strong>the</strong>y?Have Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>m policies been discussed in public <strong>for</strong>ums and <strong>the</strong> press?Do key stakeholders see <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>ms as desirable?Do Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>m champions have sufficient support and resources?Has a stakeholder analysis been conducted?Are constituencies at various societal levels organised and supportive of <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor agenda?Has <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor agenda been marketed to demonstrate its desirability and benefits?Are politicians and technocrats on board?Are representatives of <strong>the</strong> poor identified and engaged?Has opposition been addressed and overcome?Have resources been identified/obtained to pursue re<strong>for</strong>m policies?Have partnerships been <strong>for</strong>med among government, civil society organisations, community associations,and pro-poor advocates?Are donors on board with resources and technical support?Have capacity/resource gaps been identified? Steps taken to fill <strong>the</strong>m?Has implementation responsibility been assigned, and to which organisations or groups?Have implementation measures been elaborated and sequenced?Have pilot sites been identified?Do implementing organisations/groups have <strong>the</strong> appropriate capacities, missions, mandates, andresources to carry out implementation activities? If no, what modifications are required?Are new organisations/partnerships/netw<strong>ork</strong>s required?Has <strong>the</strong> design of appropriate incentives been considered and addressed?Have specifi c plans, per<strong>for</strong>mance expectations, timetables and outcomes been developed?Do <strong>the</strong>se plans include provision <strong>for</strong> early success and dissemination of success stories?Have resistance, opposition, and conflict been planned <strong>for</strong>?Are milestones in place to track progress and flag <strong>the</strong> need <strong>for</strong> adaptation?Are mechanisms established to capture lessons learned?


Table 5.6 Empowerment Domain 1: Access to JusticeFramew<strong>ork</strong> of Opportunities and ProtectionsLegal Instruments Problem <strong>for</strong> Poor People Opportunities/Protections• Universal Declaration on HumanRights (UDHR), ICCPR, CESCR• Rights related to access toin<strong>for</strong>mation; legal services;protection• Professional rules of conduct• Extracts from o<strong>the</strong>r inter-nationalhuman rights treaties (includingfundamental ILO Conventions and<strong>the</strong> Convention on indigenous andtribal peoples) conventions, UNGAresolutions, etc.• Lack of legal identity: indigenous,stateless, displaced• Ignorance of legal rights• Lack of access to legal services• Unjust & unaccountable legalinstitutions• Denial of fundamental rights• Registration drives; right tolegal identity• Increase knowledge of rights• Improve access to legalservices• Institutional re<strong>for</strong>m/legalre<strong>for</strong>m• Capacity-building ofrepresentative organisationsIn <strong>the</strong> second empowerment domain of assetholdingrights, <strong>the</strong> major issues <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poorinclude insecurity of tenure, <strong>for</strong>ced evictions,<strong>the</strong> appropriation of <strong>the</strong> rural commons by <strong>the</strong>state, confusing institutional, legal and regulatoryframew<strong>ork</strong>s, lack of access to infrastructure, basicservices and credit, and difficulty of establishingrights. Table 5.7 shows how <strong>the</strong>se might bemapped.The first task would be to identify <strong>the</strong> minimumstandard to which all human beings are entitled by<strong>the</strong>ir very humanity — in o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong> minimumfloor of protection. In <strong>the</strong> case of property rights, itwould be <strong>the</strong> ‘freedom from eviction’. No one shouldfeel threatened with being removed from <strong>the</strong>ir placeof residence without due process and compensation,including <strong>the</strong> possibility of resettlement. The mainsources of this protection include <strong>the</strong> Universal Declarationof Human Rights (UDHR), <strong>the</strong> InternationalCovenant on Civil and Political Relations (ICCPR)and <strong>the</strong> International Economic and Social Covenant(ICESR); <strong>for</strong> indigenous peoples, <strong>the</strong> Indigenousand Tribal Peoples Convention, 1989 (ILO ConventionNo. 169). In addition, <strong>the</strong>re is an internationallyrecognised ‘Right to Adequate Housing’, whichincludes security of tenure as one of its six components.New opportunities and protections <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor couldinclude systemic re<strong>for</strong>ms to legal, regulatory andinstitutional framew<strong>ork</strong>s to simplify procedures andsystems, <strong>the</strong> recognition and training of para-professionals(valuators, surveyors, etc.), extending housingmicro-finance ‘down-market’ to reach <strong>the</strong> poor, community-basedsavings linked to urban poor funds,low cost and decentralised surveying and registries ofland, recognition and registration of customary andcommon property rights in <strong>the</strong> name of rural poorand indigenous people, and freehold titles where appropriateand af<strong>for</strong>dable.The spectrum of land rights (see Box 5.5) hassome important policy implications that couldin<strong>for</strong>m a practical approach to <strong>the</strong> follow-up w<strong>ork</strong>of <strong>the</strong> Commission, namely implementing a legalempowerment agenda in <strong>the</strong> area of land rights. Agovernment could initially make a public statementor decree that residents of unauthorised settlementswill not be evicted without due process. This318


Table 5.7 Empowerment Domain 2: Property RightsFramew<strong>ork</strong> of Opportunities and ProtectionsLegal Instruments Problem <strong>for</strong> Poor People Opportunities/Protections• Universal Declaration onHuman Rights (UDHR), ICCPR,CESCR• Habitat Agenda• Right to adequate housing,including security of tenure,General Comment 4 & 7• Pinheiro Principles onRestitution of Housing, Landand Property Rights• Extract from o<strong>the</strong>r internationalhuman rights treaties,conventions, declarations, etc(in particular Indigenous andTribal Peoples Convention,1969 (ILO Convention No. 169)• Insecurity of tenure• Forced evictions• Common-property appropriatedby <strong>the</strong> state• Non-respect <strong>for</strong> rights ofindigenous and tribal peoples• Legal and institutional barriers(path to property, overlappingmandates, professionalreluctance)• Lack of access to infrastructureand basic services• Lack of access to credit• Spectrum approach to security oftenure• Guidelines to promote due process in<strong>the</strong> event of <strong>for</strong>ced evictions• Pro-poor land and agrarian re<strong>for</strong>ms• Joint titling and re<strong>for</strong>m ofdiscriminatory inheritance laws andpractices regarding land• Skills development of paraprofessionals(e.g., ‘barefootsurveyors’)• Extending housing micro-finance‘down-market’• Community-based savings linked tourban poor fundswould enable residents to invest in improvementsto <strong>the</strong>ir home and community that would havebeneficial side effects on o<strong>the</strong>r aspects of <strong>the</strong>ir life,particularly health. As resources permit, securitycould be increased, facilitating fur<strong>the</strong>r investments.This incremental process would help ensurethat <strong>the</strong> tenure increases take place at <strong>the</strong> pace of<strong>the</strong> urban poor and do not unintentionally result in‘downward raiding’ by <strong>the</strong> middle-class — possiblyresulting in market-based evictions of <strong>the</strong> poor.On <strong>the</strong> labour rights front, <strong>the</strong> major concern ishow to ensure decent w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> all. The poor facenon-respect <strong>for</strong> fundamental principles and rightsat w<strong>ork</strong>, a lack of legal recognition of w<strong>ork</strong>ers and<strong>the</strong>ir organisations in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy (andto some extent in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy), institutionaland regulatory issues, unsafe w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions,<strong>the</strong> specific problems of vulnerable groups such aschildren, and <strong>the</strong> lack of social security and protection.As in <strong>the</strong> case of land, w<strong>ork</strong>ers find <strong>the</strong>mselvesin a range of situations, from those in which <strong>the</strong>yare denied all opportunities (being subjected to<strong>for</strong>ced labour) to those in which <strong>the</strong>y enjoy opportunities<strong>for</strong> full and productive employment, accompaniedby basic security. Unlike land <strong>the</strong> spectrum<strong>for</strong> legal empowerment in relation to rights at w<strong>ork</strong>should focus on <strong>the</strong> extent of opportunity/protectionenjoyed by a particular w<strong>ork</strong>er or group of w<strong>ork</strong>ers.This is to avoid <strong>for</strong>mal legal classifications (‘casualw<strong>ork</strong>’, ‘independent contractor’, etc.) which varyacross legal systems. Fundamental principles andrights at w<strong>ork</strong> are particularly vital in <strong>the</strong> market <strong>for</strong>unskilled labour that is <strong>the</strong> main source of income<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor.In relation to labour issues, protection/security andopportunities could be mapped along an ‘upwardsarrow’ spectrum towards decent w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> all (fulland freely chosen productive employment, carriedout in conditions of dignity, equity and security).Fundamental principles governing w<strong>ork</strong> (e.g.,freedom of association, freedom from <strong>for</strong>ced labour,child labour and discrimination) involve both319


Box 5.6 Gold Rush in Mongolia: from Herders to ‘Ninjas’Harsh winters in Mongolia have been <strong>for</strong>cing traditionalherder families to eke out a living as in<strong>for</strong>mal miners.W<strong>ork</strong>ers laid off from <strong>for</strong>mal mining sites were <strong>the</strong> firstto mine in<strong>for</strong>mally. From <strong>the</strong> green plastic containers<strong>the</strong>y wear on <strong>the</strong>ir backs in turtle style, <strong>the</strong>y are knownas ‘ninjas’. An estimated 100,000 men, women andchildren engage in in<strong>for</strong>mal mining (<strong>the</strong> entire populationis only 2.7 million), producing <strong>the</strong> same level as <strong>for</strong>malmining companies. Exposure to mercury used to extractgold from <strong>the</strong> ore puts <strong>the</strong> miners, especially <strong>the</strong> children,at serious risk.The Mongolian Employers Federation (MONEF) has beenseeking a new law to govern in<strong>for</strong>mal mining. At <strong>the</strong> sametime, it has been raising awareness among <strong>the</strong> miningcompanies and providing chances <strong>for</strong> children of miningfamilies to receive education and training. Tripartitenegotiations (involving government, and employers’ andw<strong>ork</strong>ers’ representatives) agreed on changes to labour legislationthat would extend its reach to those in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy and improve protection against <strong>the</strong> worst <strong>for</strong>msof child labour. So far, however, <strong>the</strong>se initiatives have notbeen enacted into law.Such measures would help to fill a legislative gap thatemerged at <strong>the</strong> time of privatisation of mining in <strong>the</strong>1990s. Legislation on mining minerals and <strong>the</strong> peoplewho mine <strong>the</strong>m provides an opportunity <strong>for</strong> coherencebetween policies on natural resource use, investment,property ownership, job creation <strong>for</strong> adults and labourprotection.Source: Damdinjav Narmandakh, ‘Extending labour protection to <strong>the</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy in Mongolia,’ in David Tajgman, ed., ExtendingLabour <strong>Law</strong> to All W<strong>ork</strong>ers: Promoting Decent W<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>malEconomy in Cambodia, Thailand and Mongolia (ILO, Bangkok, 2006),pp 105-153; ‘Gold rush in Mongolia: When shepherds become‘ninjas’.’ ILO: About <strong>the</strong> ILO, 2 Sept. 2005.opportunities and protections. For example, <strong>the</strong>legal protection prohibiting children from engagingin <strong>the</strong> worst <strong>for</strong>ms of child labour (that can stunt<strong>the</strong>ir growth and condemn <strong>the</strong>m to a life of povertyas unskilled w<strong>ork</strong>ers) needs to be accompanied byopportunities to attend school and acquire marketableskills.Similarly, <strong>the</strong> exercise of freedom of associationgoes hand in hand with legal protections thatpermit easy registration of trade unions, smallemployers, cooperatives and small traders’ associations,whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y are in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal or in<strong>for</strong>maleconomies. The security/protection dimension hasobvious relevance in relation to protecting w<strong>ork</strong>ers’health and ensuring a social floor that keeps <strong>the</strong>mfrom falling back into poverty when a family heal<strong>the</strong>mergency strikes. For example, <strong>the</strong> Zambian Congressof Trade Unions and <strong>the</strong> Alliance <strong>for</strong> ZambiaIn<strong>for</strong>mal Economy Associations launched a partnershipin 2002. (Ano<strong>the</strong>r illustration from Mongoliais presented in Box 5.6.) Moreover, <strong>the</strong> ability toachieve decent w<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> all will be conditioned by<strong>the</strong> job-creating or job-destroying effects of internationaland national macroeconomic policies, sothis dimension would need to be captured as wellTable 5.8 shows how labour rights can be mappedwith <strong>the</strong> protection and security available in variouslegal and o<strong>the</strong>r instruments and with <strong>the</strong> opportunitiesand protections implicit in <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor agenda.Establishing entrepreneurial rights also impliesa broad policy re<strong>for</strong>m agenda (Table 5.9). Within<strong>the</strong> mandate of <strong>the</strong> Commission, <strong>the</strong> major issues<strong>for</strong> poor business people include lack of recognitionand vulnerability, lack of credit and capital,absence of social security, lack of protection oflabour and of assets, and institutional barriers to<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal economy such as complicated procedures(entry/exit, expansion of business contracts,conflict resolution). There would be a possiblespectrum from <strong>the</strong> street hawker or fisher without320


Table 5.8 Empowerment Domain 3: Labour RightsFramew<strong>ork</strong> of Opportunities and ProtectionsLegal and O<strong>the</strong>r Instruments Problem <strong>for</strong> Poor People Opportunities/Protections• Universal Declaration onHuman Rights (UDHR), CESPR,CCPR• ILO Conventions• Extracts from o<strong>the</strong>rinternational human rightstreaties, declarations, etc.• Rights to decent w<strong>ork</strong>/livelihoods• National labour laws• Collective bargainingagreements• Some corporate codes ofconduct• Earnings inadequate to supportfamily• Lack of recognition• Denial of freedom ofassociation• Institutional barriers/issues• Unsafe w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions• Child labour• Forced/bonded labour• Discrimination• Barriers to combining w<strong>ork</strong> andfamily• Lack of social security/protection• Low productivity and long hours• Productive employment with higherincomes• Skill acquisition/upgrading• Balanced regulation of subcontracting• Improved en<strong>for</strong>cement mechanismsand o<strong>the</strong>r institutions• Legal framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> stronger collectiverepresentation• Minimum package of labour rights <strong>for</strong>in<strong>for</strong>mal economy w<strong>ork</strong>ers• Innovations in social protection• Measures <strong>for</strong> gender and indigenousequity• Rapid, efficient and low-cost disputeresolution mechanismsassets, to <strong>the</strong> petty trader, <strong>the</strong> mobile hairdresser,<strong>the</strong> shopkeeper or tea-shop owner to <strong>the</strong> smallbusiness person with less than five employees,and <strong>the</strong> larger <strong>for</strong>mal sector business. All <strong>the</strong>sedifferent entrepreneurs require different levels ofprotection and access to different kinds of opportunities.Examples of <strong>the</strong>se rules and institutions areguarantees of fundamental rights, member-basedorganisations, cooperatives, access to financialservices, social security innovations, insurance,credit, equity and capital.These questions become even more important because<strong>the</strong> Commission’s intent is not to push legalTable 5.9 Empowerment Domain 4: Business RightsFramew<strong>ork</strong> of Opportunities and ProtectionsLegal Instruments Problem <strong>for</strong> Poor People Opportunities/Protections• Universal Declaration onHuman Rights (UDHR)• Rights to livelihoods• Right to development• Extract from o<strong>the</strong>r internationalhuman rights treaties,conventions, declarations, etc.• Lack of recognition-vulnerability• Institutional barriers to <strong>for</strong>maleconomy: Complicated procedures(entry/exit, expansion of businesscontracts, conflict resolution)• Health and environmental risks• Lack of credit and capital• Lack of social security/protection• Registration• Member-based organisations(associations, cooperatives)• Access to credit, equity andcapitalisation• Rapid, efficient and low-costdispute resolution mechanisms• Social security deficits (insurance)321


e<strong>for</strong>ms, per se, but legal empowerment of <strong>the</strong>poor. Policy changes must provide poor people withan institutional environment that offers protection,and in addition, provides incentives so that <strong>the</strong>ycan develop <strong>the</strong>ir full capabilities as individuals.This becomes a difficult agenda to implement becausein too many developing countries, rights thatare well articulated in legislation are simply notrespected; in o<strong>the</strong>r developing countries, <strong>the</strong>re iswell-functioning statutory legal regime, but it oftenmainly serves <strong>the</strong> interests of <strong>the</strong> middle and upperincome brackets. In some cases, <strong>the</strong> same law canbe used against <strong>the</strong> poor.We should also make mention of <strong>the</strong> legalregimes based on customary and sometimesreligious rules and social compacts. These are welldescribed and increasingly rely on some <strong>for</strong>m ofdocumentation nested in local institutions, but notrecognised by statutory law. It is <strong>the</strong> poor, as previouslydiscussed, who typically use <strong>the</strong>se regimes.Formal institutions and regulations are too complex,with technical standards set too high. Thelack of legal identity cuts off access to basic opportunities,such as education. At <strong>the</strong> same time,lack of identity exposes <strong>the</strong> poor to harassment andviolence. Ignorance and illiteracy prevent accessingopportunities and ensuring en<strong>for</strong>cement oflegal obligations. Special opportunity-measures areoften required <strong>for</strong> women and <strong>the</strong> more vulnerablegroups, including children and indigenous peoples.to local realities. This section presents a framew<strong>ork</strong><strong>for</strong> discussing <strong>the</strong> potential activities that couldbe undertaken at <strong>the</strong> global, regional national andlocal levels to support <strong>the</strong> implementation of <strong>the</strong>Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor agenda.Table 5.10 presents an indicative summary ofpotential strategies and activities to be consideredin <strong>the</strong> implementation of <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor agenda at <strong>the</strong> global, regional nationaland local levels.Activities at global levelActivities at global level would likely focus on twotypes of activities to support Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor at <strong>the</strong> country level: advocacy andknowledge management. The <strong>for</strong>mer would focuson getting key messages out to important targetaudiences through a variety of vehicles. For <strong>the</strong>World Bank’s World Development Report, a periodof six months is usually allocated to promoting <strong>the</strong>key messages after <strong>the</strong> launch date. A website, or a‘brand/logo’ that can be added to existing websites,would become <strong>the</strong> future repository of <strong>the</strong> followupto <strong>the</strong> Commission, providing updates and progressreports on how <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor agenda is being implemented. An inventoryof evidence on capacity development in domainssimilar to Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor wouldbe compiled, and dialogue would be supported todisseminate global good practices.Mapping <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor Agenda at Different Political/Administrative LevelsThere is also a need <strong>for</strong> ‘global public goods’ or activitiesundertaken at <strong>the</strong> global level that will havean important role to play in supporting countrylevelactivities. Moreover, as <strong>the</strong> Commission itselfhas stated, important differences exist betweencountries and even between regions that also call<strong>for</strong> a flexible, demand-driven approach appropriate322Knowledge management activities would build oninitial inventories of good practice, on-going initiativesand actors engaged in promoting empowermentcollected through <strong>the</strong> process of preparing <strong>the</strong>Commission’s report. A key element would be toidentify existing indicators and monitoring ef<strong>for</strong>ts tofur<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor agenda.Similarly, and particularly in <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong> rightsto justice and asset holding, evaluations <strong>for</strong> learningwill be vital.


Table 5.10 LEP Implementation Strategies and Indicative ActivitiesPolitical/Admin.LevelWorldAdvocacy• High Level Meetingwithin <strong>the</strong> framew<strong>ork</strong>of <strong>the</strong> UN• Identify globalprinciples of LegalEmpowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor and promoteas vehicle <strong>for</strong>poverty reduction• Media strategy andcampaign promotingLegal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Pooragenda• Mobilise donors• Target setting inrelation to 2015• Periodic reports onstate of Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong>Poor• WebsiteKnowledgeManagement• Inventory of existinginitiatives andactors• Inventory existingevaluations andanalyse lessons• Develop analyticalframew<strong>ork</strong>s <strong>for</strong>evaluation (includingfrom gender/indigenousperspectives)• Developing indicatorsand Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong>Poor monitoring• Streng<strong>the</strong>n statisticalbases <strong>for</strong> contextualanalysis• Establish supportnetw<strong>ork</strong>s of professionals,academics,etc.Pilot Initiatives• Develop countryselection criteria• Conduct globalsurvey• Engage in dialoguewith potential countriesand supportorganisations• Develop Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong>Poor interventionlogic and strategy(logical framew<strong>ork</strong>approach)• Develop assessmenttools• Gender audit• Use Poverty ReductionStrategies andDecent W<strong>ork</strong> CountryProgrammemesCapacity Development• Advocacy to changeorganisationaland managementpractices to favourLegal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor• Inventory of existingcapacity-buildingprogrammemes• Inventory of toolkits,tools and methodsto support implementation• Undertake capacityneeds/gap assessmentRegion andsub-region• Regional and subregionaladvocacystrategies with relevantpolitical andfinancial bodies• Regional SocialContracts• Ministerial meetings• Awareness raising• Sharing of RegionalBest Practice• Regional progressmonitoring• Regional reports• Cooperation betweenimplementingcountries,development banks,and political andeconomic regionalinstitutions• Peer-exchangeswithin and betweenregions• Knowledge plat<strong>for</strong>mon capacity developmentand evaluativeevidenceIn addition, a range of activities would be undertakento prepare <strong>for</strong> country-level w<strong>ork</strong>. Countriesand international support organisations wouldbe identified to support <strong>the</strong> process of changeat country level. Resources would be mobilised.Pro-poor toolkits and methods to support capacity-buildingwould also be inventoried and gapsidentified. These would be made available througha variety of avenues — websites, w<strong>ork</strong>shops, etc.Activities at <strong>the</strong> Regional andSub-regional LevelsAt <strong>the</strong> regional and sub-regional levels, activitieswould also likely focus on advocacy and knowledgemanagement. The region and sub-region arecritical <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> success of <strong>the</strong> legal empowermentagenda; it is at <strong>the</strong>se levels that global norms canbe adapted to different socio-economic contexts.Building political will <strong>for</strong> change will occur through323


Table 5.10 LEP Implementation Strategies and Indicative Activities cont.Political/Admin.LevelNationAdvocacy• National Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong>Poor Campaigns• Integrate LegalEmpowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor intopoverty reductionstrategies/ nationaldevelopment plans/decent w<strong>ork</strong> countryprogrammemesKnowledgeManagement• Establishingbaselines andmonitoring progressregarding LegalEmpowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor• Situation Analyses• Thematic studies• Who’s doing whatwhere in Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong>PoorPilot Initiatives• Pilot countries step<strong>for</strong>ward/ are identified• Pilot initiativesCapacity Development• Inventory of existingsupport structuresand needs• Collaboration withprofessional orgsand academia totrain grassrootsprofessionals• Set up and activate<strong>for</strong>ums <strong>for</strong> stateinterface with <strong>the</strong>poorLocality• Rights awareness• In<strong>for</strong>mation campaigns• Opportunitiesawareness• Identifying grassrootsexperience• Identifying partners• Pilot initiatives inup to four <strong>the</strong>maticareas• Support to grassroots/communitybasedorganisations• Support to grassrootsprofessionalsand para-professionals• Facilitate communityengagementtechniques and<strong>for</strong>umsregional and sub-regional organisations (e.g.African Union, ASEAN, etc.), U.N. Regional Commissions(e.g. ECA, ESCAP, ECLAC), sub-regionalbodies such as SADAC, Mercosur and in partnershipwith regional development banks (AfricanDevelopment Bank, Asian Development Bank, Inter-AmericanDevelopment Bank). A series of new‘Regional Social Contracts’ could be an importantmechanism to <strong>for</strong>ge political consensus on <strong>the</strong>legal empowerment agenda.of <strong>the</strong> Poor. For example, francophone countries inWest Africa are already taking steps to streamline<strong>the</strong>ir commercial codes under <strong>the</strong> framew<strong>ork</strong> of<strong>the</strong> Organisation <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Harmonisation of AfricanBusiness <strong>Law</strong>. In terms of implementation, peerexchangemechanisms can facilitate <strong>the</strong> sharing ofcountry level experience in policy re<strong>for</strong>m.Activities at National LevelImplementation of empowering policies ideallyExisting ministerial <strong>for</strong>ums could be good opportunitiestakes place at <strong>the</strong> national level, where <strong>the</strong> chanceto promote Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor and is greatest to have wide impact on poverty; how-existing peer-exchange mechanisms will be possibleever, <strong>the</strong> aim should probably not be to establishplat<strong>for</strong>ms <strong>for</strong> aggregating regional demand <strong>for</strong> a ‘legal empowerment programmeme’ as a standever,national re<strong>for</strong>ms. Forums already engaged in law re<strong>for</strong>malone entity; ra<strong>the</strong>r, it should be to integrate Legalamong countries would have a natural interest Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor into existing processes,in <strong>the</strong> issues being raised by Legal Empowerment such as <strong>the</strong> preparation of national development324


plans, poverty reduction strategies (PRSs), UNDevelopment Assistance Framew<strong>ork</strong>s (UNDAFs),etc. Ano<strong>the</strong>r important dimension of national levelw<strong>ork</strong> will involve w<strong>ork</strong>ing closely with professionalassociations (lawyers, surveyors, planners, localauthorities, micro-finance institutions, Chambers ofCommerce, labour unions, farmers’ organisations,etc.) to create a new generation of professionals in<strong>the</strong> spirit of <strong>the</strong> ‘barefoot engineers’ that have beenpioneered in South Asia. 9Activities at <strong>the</strong> Local LevelWithout support from <strong>the</strong> base organisations of <strong>the</strong>poor, <strong>the</strong>re is little chance of realising <strong>the</strong> LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor agenda. Involving <strong>the</strong>segroups in <strong>the</strong> design of interventions of any kind(advocacy, knowledge management, pilot initiatives,and capacity development) is crucial. In<strong>for</strong>mationdissemination will be a central strategy at<strong>the</strong> local level. In some countries with particularlyweak or oppressive national governments, communityempowerment activities may be <strong>the</strong> onlyfeasible ones. Where social mobilisation is strong,however, <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agenda can bebuilt, bottom-up, by supporting existing initiativesof <strong>the</strong> urban poor, such as <strong>the</strong> pioneering urbanpoor funds in Cambodia, India and elsewhere.4. Country LevelApproaches, Toolkits andIndicesThe pathways to Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorare multi-tiered with many possible intersections,roundabouts, dead-ends, detours, and shortcuts.Given <strong>the</strong> options, carrying out Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor takes a variety of different country-levelapproaches, tools or specific techniques<strong>for</strong> manipulating <strong>the</strong> ‘how’ of policy. For countriespromoting <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment agenda, identifying<strong>the</strong> appropriate process, picking <strong>the</strong> righttools and establishing <strong>the</strong> appropriate benchmarks<strong>for</strong> success are critical.Countries Piloting LegalEmpowerment Re<strong>for</strong>mThere has been a tremendous positive responsearound <strong>the</strong> world to <strong>the</strong> idea of pro-poor legalempowerment. As <strong>the</strong> Commission moves from <strong>the</strong>global to <strong>the</strong> country level, a process must be developedto enable, where appropriate, <strong>the</strong> matchingof <strong>the</strong> demand <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m with <strong>the</strong> appropriatesupply of in<strong>for</strong>mation, expertise and experience.Different countries will wish to take different pathsto legal empowerment. Some of <strong>the</strong> critical issuesthat countries and <strong>the</strong>ir development partners willhave to address are:Historical and social context: The objectives oflegal empowerment aim at achieving systemicchange in <strong>the</strong> relations between <strong>the</strong> poor, <strong>the</strong> stateand <strong>the</strong> market. The historic context will greatlyaffect <strong>the</strong> possibility to achieve change of thismagnitude and <strong>the</strong> timing should be carefully considered.Is <strong>the</strong> country ready to undertake <strong>the</strong> legalempowerment challenge? Comparing data regardingeconomic growth, inequality and social exclusion,and poverty will be important in assessing <strong>the</strong>325


need and <strong>the</strong> potential <strong>for</strong> success.Political will: As <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m agenda affects <strong>the</strong>institutions and structures of government, highlevel political support must be ensured. Evidenceof government commitment will include addition oflegal empowerment to national development plans,poverty reduction strategies and, perhaps mostimportantly, national budget allocations.Grass-roots and civil society capacity: To sustain<strong>the</strong> momentum <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m will require <strong>the</strong> activeand sustained support of civil society, perhapsmore than any o<strong>the</strong>r entity with <strong>the</strong> exception ofgovernment. Assessing its capacity to drive andsustain change is critical.Governance: The quality of governance — <strong>the</strong>processes, rules and organisations supportingdevelopment — will have an important bearingon <strong>the</strong> likelihood of success in implementing LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. The relations betweengovernment, civil society and <strong>the</strong> professional andprivate sectors will make or break <strong>the</strong> chances <strong>for</strong>success. Political risk mapping and stakeholderanalysis will be useful tools <strong>for</strong> managing politicalrisk.External support: Legal empowerment processesmust be nationally owned, but outsiders can playan important role in supporting <strong>the</strong> quality of <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>m process and in helping to deliver specificoutputs that will build <strong>the</strong> momentum <strong>for</strong> change.Assessing donor interest and <strong>the</strong> capacity of externalsupport organisations will be important.Choosing <strong>the</strong> appropriate country levelprocessA variety of options exist <strong>for</strong> countries, and <strong>the</strong>organisations that support <strong>the</strong>m, to drive <strong>the</strong> legalempowerment agenda. The option chosen willdepend on <strong>the</strong> specific country context and will beaffected by such factors as <strong>the</strong> strength of civil society,private sector and donor interest, date of <strong>the</strong>next elections, preparation of national developmentstrategy, and o<strong>the</strong>r time sensitive issues affecting<strong>the</strong> policy window. Options include:• National civil society or academia collect in<strong>for</strong>mationand get specific issues, such as LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor, into <strong>the</strong> policy debateand on <strong>the</strong> table.• Governments develop projects in a department/ministry as part of <strong>the</strong>ir on going developmentplans and programmemes, independent of donorsupport.• Governments and donors agree on specific legalempowerment projects. These can include <strong>the</strong>establishment of project implementation unitswhose intent is to facilitate on-<strong>the</strong>-job trainingof government officials or, more direct methods,such as establishing an implementation cell ina senior office, possibly even <strong>the</strong> Office of <strong>the</strong>President. In so doing, care should be takennot to sideline o<strong>the</strong>r institutions that may needstreng<strong>the</strong>ning, such as law re<strong>for</strong>m commissions.• Building on national re<strong>for</strong>m processes in any of<strong>the</strong> four legal empowerment domains, rangingacross broad national processes such as nationaldevelopment plans or poverty reduction strategies.• Establishing multi-stakeholder processes thatinclude government, civil society and externalpartners. One such example is <strong>the</strong> country-leveladaptation of <strong>the</strong> Harmonisation, Alignment andCoordination (HAC) process emerging from <strong>the</strong>2005 Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness (seeBox 5.7 describing <strong>the</strong> Kenya HAC process in<strong>the</strong> land sector). Donors can choose from a widevariety of funding mechanisms to support thisprocess, ranging from direct budget support to<strong>the</strong> establishment of basket funds.• Using <strong>the</strong> coordination and funding mechanisms326


Box 5.7 Land Sector Harmonisation, Alignment andCoordination <strong>for</strong> Poverty Reduction in KenyaIn line with <strong>the</strong> new agenda on aid effectiveness, <strong>the</strong>Development Partners Group on Land (DPGL) aims todeliver and manage aid to <strong>the</strong> land sector in Kenya asto meet <strong>the</strong> principles of harmonisation, alignment andcoordination (HAC). In its activities and cooperationwith o<strong>the</strong>r stakeholders, <strong>the</strong> DPGL strives to achieveconsensus and support around <strong>the</strong> policy direction of<strong>the</strong> government instead of pursuing diverging agendas.The emphasis of <strong>the</strong> group is on three areas: 1) streng<strong>the</strong>ninggovernment capacity to develop and implementland-related policies and programmemes; 2) aligningdonor support with government priorities as set out inits poverty reduction strategy (PRS), and 3) avoidingduplication and overlapping in aid initiatives. The landsector donor group was officially <strong>for</strong>med in July 2003 andit has up until 2006 channelled support to <strong>the</strong> NationalLand Policy Formulation Process through a Basket Fundarrangement. Since its establishment, <strong>the</strong> donor grouphas supported <strong>the</strong> government with investments worth ofUS$10 million in <strong>the</strong> land sector.The support of <strong>the</strong> DPGL is now expanding beyondpolicy development to cover <strong>the</strong> main activities run by<strong>the</strong> Ministry of Land through <strong>the</strong> Land Re<strong>for</strong>m SupportProgrammeme (LRSP). The LRSP incorporates elementsrelating to <strong>the</strong> finalisation of <strong>the</strong> land policy process,policy implementation, institutional trans<strong>for</strong>mation, <strong>the</strong>development of a pro-poor Land In<strong>for</strong>mation ManagementSystems (LIMS), <strong>the</strong> implementation of <strong>the</strong> recommendationsof <strong>the</strong> Ndungu Commission on illegal allocationof public land and <strong>the</strong> development of Forced EvictionGuidelines in Kenya.These and o<strong>the</strong>r activities have collectively supported<strong>the</strong> Government’s economic recovery strategy (i.e.,PRSP) as well as <strong>the</strong> government’s ef<strong>for</strong>ts to realise<strong>the</strong> Millennium Development Goals, particularly relatingto <strong>the</strong> Eradication of Extreme Poverty and Hunger(MDG 1), Promotion of Gender Equality and Empowermentof Women (MDG 3), and Ensuring EnvironmentalSustainability (MDG 7). Development Partners financiallysupporting <strong>the</strong> Basket Fund initiative have been DFID(UK), SIDA (Sweden), DCI (Irish Aid) and USAID. O<strong>the</strong>rdevelopment partners involved in <strong>the</strong> land sector inKenya include JICA, <strong>the</strong> Embassies of Finland and Italyy,<strong>the</strong> World Bank, as well as UN related agencies such as<strong>the</strong> FAO, UNDP, and UNEP.Source: Adapted from UN-HABITAT (2007) Global Report on HumanSettlements 2007: Enhancing Urban Safety and Security,London, Earthscan, p. 154established in post-disaster or post-conflict contextsto support <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m process.After deciding on <strong>the</strong> general tack to take with regardto Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor, countrieswill likely need to agree on a more detailed process<strong>for</strong> managing <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m process. This process willoften include a series of steps as outlined below.These are not necessarily sequential and severalsteps may have to be repeated over time as <strong>the</strong>situation changes.• Mobilising stakeholders: Identifying key stakeholdersand agreeing on a process and a setof principles to guide <strong>the</strong> legal empowermentagenda will be a critical step to build confidenceamong stakeholders. Key issues will include coordinationmechanisms, adoption of a protocol oragreement, and clarification of roles and responsibilities,and agreement on a broad process <strong>for</strong>re<strong>for</strong>m;• Situation analysis or legal empowerment diagnostic:A detailed assessment should be madeof <strong>the</strong> relevant issues to be addressed, including<strong>the</strong> relevant aspects of each of <strong>the</strong> four legal empowermentdomains. The analysis will identifypolicy, legal and institutional issues, as well asgaps in resources, capacity and tools.327


• Action planning: Development of <strong>the</strong> goal,objectives, strategies, and specific interventionsthat will contribute to <strong>the</strong> legal empowermentobjective. Critical issues will include sequencingand timing, resource constraints, establishing amonitoring and evaluation framew<strong>ork</strong> and ensuringa balance between process and products tomaintain momentum.• Pilot activities: These should be built around<strong>the</strong> idea of ‘quick wins’ — outputs — in areaswhere <strong>the</strong>se are feasible. In this way one canbuild <strong>the</strong> credibility of <strong>the</strong> legal empowermentagenda and demonstrate some initial success.Pilot activities could include a mix of practicalre<strong>for</strong>ms in each of <strong>the</strong> domains, policy analysis(e.g., ‘path to property’ analysis), advocacy andawareness, in<strong>for</strong>mation collection and streng<strong>the</strong>ningcoordination mechanisms.• Scaling-up: Expanding <strong>the</strong> range of activities andtaking on more complicated challenges. Raisingawareness of past successes, additional sensitisation,streng<strong>the</strong>ning <strong>the</strong> consultation processwill all support this stage. Evaluations may beuseful tools here.• Institutionalising change and <strong>the</strong> change process:Tackling some of <strong>the</strong> fundamental re<strong>for</strong>msby building on <strong>the</strong> experiences in <strong>the</strong> pilot phaseand scaling-up phase to re<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> organisationsand rules that shape <strong>the</strong> institutional context.Tools to support legal empowermentre<strong>for</strong>msAfter deciding on <strong>the</strong> general approach to be takenwith Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor, re<strong>for</strong>mersneed to consider numerous applied techniques,developed by anti-poverty w<strong>ork</strong>ers, communityorganisers and re<strong>for</strong>m advocates around <strong>the</strong> world<strong>for</strong> carrying out activities analogous to <strong>the</strong> Commission’sempowerment agenda. Table 5.11 summarisessome of <strong>the</strong> pertinent pro-poor policy tools,sorting <strong>the</strong>m out according to <strong>the</strong> implementationphases where <strong>the</strong>y are most, but not exclusively,applicable. These implementation techniques aregeneral, flexible and easy to modify; developmentpractitioners will need to screen out those toolsthat do not apply to <strong>the</strong>ir situation, and selectthose that are w<strong>ork</strong>able in <strong>the</strong> particular countrycontext and suitable <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> particular task at hand.Explanation of <strong>the</strong> toolsThree tools (stakeholder analysis, contextualanalysis, and policy characteristics analysis)have already been covered at some length in Section2. All <strong>the</strong> tools are annotated in alphabeticalorder in Annex 1 (and <strong>the</strong> tools <strong>for</strong> action planningand monitoring are explained fur<strong>the</strong>r in Section 5).Readers are also referred to <strong>the</strong> numerous toolkitsdeveloped by international organisations and NGOs<strong>for</strong> organising communities and implementingnumerous aspects of social and economic developmentpolicy (see <strong>the</strong> footnote below and Annex 2<strong>for</strong> a comprehensive inventory of toolkits). 10 Manyof <strong>the</strong>se tools can be used individually or in combinationin <strong>the</strong> implementation of Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>ms. On this basis, a set ofLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor indicators can bedeveloped, tailored to country circumstances.Ready-made Indicators of LegalEmpowermentBoth <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mulation and monitoring phases ofLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor implementationdepend on indicators of democratisation, good governance,human rights protection, and many o<strong>the</strong>rvariables related to legal empowerment. There hasbeen a quantitative revolution in recent years ofinternationally comparable data on political andregulatory institutions. There are now at least 150measures of different aspects of governance in <strong>the</strong>public domain. These data series are of variable328


quality and utility in establishing rough baselines<strong>for</strong> governance among <strong>the</strong> nations of <strong>the</strong> world;<strong>the</strong>y are not sufficiently developed to be of greatvalue in measuring changes in <strong>the</strong> political or legalstatus of a country’s poor men and women overtime. They are also highly aggregate and thus oflimited utility in ascertaining empowerment in aparticular sub-national community or region.While not perfect, perhaps <strong>the</strong> best example ofinternational indexes relevant to Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor is <strong>the</strong> World Bank’s GovernanceResearch Indicator series. These are based onseveral hundred individual variables measuringperceptions of governance. They are organised intosix categories: rule of law, lack of political violence,quality of <strong>the</strong> regulatory framew<strong>ork</strong>, efficiency of<strong>the</strong> bureaucracy, control of corruption and accountabilityof <strong>the</strong> political leaders. 11 The World Bank’sdata have <strong>the</strong>ir uses but must be applied verycautiously in development w<strong>ork</strong> (Arndt and Oman2006). The Eurostat/UNDP (2004) users’ guide togovernance indicators describes at length <strong>the</strong> applicationsand limitations of several of <strong>the</strong> leadingoff-<strong>the</strong>-rack governance data series.Pending reliable pre-existing empirical in<strong>for</strong>mationon national or local-level legal empowerment,Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor programmemesand projects will have to develop and use <strong>the</strong>ir ownmetrics <strong>for</strong> evaluating <strong>the</strong> socio-economic environmentand gauging accomplishments, based onsurveys and interviews, as discussed above. RuthAlsop and Nina Heinsohn (2006) report to <strong>the</strong>World Bank on one such analytic framew<strong>ork</strong> thatcan be used to measure and monitor empowermentprocesses and outcomes. Kucera et al. (2007) put<strong>for</strong>ward indicators that have been tested <strong>for</strong> measuringvarious aspects of decent w<strong>ork</strong>. (See Annex3 <strong>for</strong> a list of readymade indicators.)5. Monitoring andEvaluationBecause action planning and progress monitoring(<strong>the</strong> final row in Table 5.11) has not beendiscussed much in <strong>the</strong>se pages, and becausethis function is especially important <strong>for</strong> outsideagencies, some of its tools are worth looking at abit more closely. Brinkerhoff and Crosby (2002)identify four components to establish an efficientparticipatory and country-driven policy monitoringsystem:1. A management in<strong>for</strong>mation system based ontargeted indicators endorsed by national stakeholders.2. Stakeholder monitoring to identify <strong>the</strong> responsesof those that benefited or those that lost from<strong>the</strong> policy re<strong>for</strong>m measures.3. Problem-solving studies to devise tailored andpractical solutions to implementation issues.4. Process and impact evaluations to supportlearning over time.Best practices recommend that <strong>the</strong> design of eachcomponent should be based on <strong>the</strong> principlesof adaptation to user needs and availability ofresources, user participation, parsimony (<strong>the</strong> leastamount of in<strong>for</strong>mation and cost required to accomplish<strong>the</strong> task), and simplicity. To address both<strong>the</strong> content and process sides in monitoring policyimplementation, it is important to understand fullywhat needs to be monitored.Lessons learned from country experiences have ledto <strong>the</strong> following practical suggestions <strong>for</strong> monitoringpolicy re<strong>for</strong>m implementation, according toBrinkerhoff and Crosby (2002):1. Define a list of steps, processes, targets andmilestone events in <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m process. Thiswill enable <strong>the</strong> breakdown of <strong>the</strong> policy processesinto a series of components to enable329


Table 5.11 Pro-poor policy implementation tools*Implementation phaseDeveloping policy issues,agendas, and decisionsPolicy <strong>for</strong>mulation andlegitimisationConstituency buildingResource mobilisationImplementation design andorganisational developmentAction planning andprogress monitoringPossible toolsCompetencies AssessmentContextual analysisLegal and institutional framew<strong>ork</strong>Opportunity RankingPolicy characteristics analysisPolitical will and risk analysisProblem CensusProblem treeSocial Baseline StudySocial Impact and Opportunities AssessmentCommunity MappingFocus groupsForce field analysisInfluence mappingInstitutional AnalysisParticipatory Poverty AssessmentsPolicy briefingsPolitical mappingStakeholder analysisStrategic Planning Framew<strong>ork</strong>/SWOT/PESTConflict prevention and resolutionNational symposiumOutreach (Media Campaigns, School Programmemes, Public SpeakingEngagements, Publications, Public Hearings, Study Circles)W<strong>ork</strong>shopsAdvocacy/lobbyingDomestic resource mobilisationFundraisingParticipatory budgetingBest practices (collection, dissemination)ExchangesInstitutional twinningInternship programmemesPara-professionalsPlain language (translation and dissemination of laws)Technical assistanceTraining (on leadership, group w<strong>ork</strong> and related management issues)Travel grants/internships <strong>for</strong> officialsWeb-based supportGender auditImpact evaluationLogical framew<strong>ork</strong> approachMISProblem solving studiesStakeholder monitoring (household surveys, key in<strong>for</strong>mant interviews)* Guide to <strong>the</strong> techniques that might be appropriate during <strong>the</strong> implementation cycle; a technique may be useful in more than one phase of implementation.Highlighted tools are described in Section 2 of this chapter.


Table 5.12 A Framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> a Demand-Led Assessment of ImplementationAccess toJusticeE.g., To whatextent does <strong>the</strong>law recognize<strong>the</strong> right of apoor person tobe registeredat birth?E.g., In <strong>the</strong>instant case,how af<strong>for</strong>dablewas <strong>the</strong>registrationprocess to <strong>the</strong>poor persons?Asset holdingRightsE.g., To whatextent does<strong>the</strong> law protectpoor tenantsfrom eviction?Labour RightsEntrepreneurialRightsE.g., To whatextent does <strong>the</strong>law mandate <strong>the</strong>reduction of costof registering abusiness belongingto a poor person?E.g., in <strong>the</strong> instantcase to what extenthas <strong>the</strong> relevantgovernment agencydecentralisedits businessregistration processto give access to<strong>the</strong> poor?CapacityDevelopmentE.g., To whatextent does <strong>the</strong>law mandategovernmentinstitution tosimplify procedures<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor?E.g., To whatextent does <strong>the</strong>governmentprovide training toits staff on legalempowerment of<strong>the</strong> poor?E.g., To whatextent does <strong>the</strong>governmentprovide accessibleguidance to <strong>the</strong>poor on servicesavailable to <strong>the</strong>mfrom governmentagencies?<strong>Law</strong>E.g., To whatextent does<strong>the</strong> lawextend labourstandards to<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomy?E.g., to whatextent does<strong>the</strong> relevantgovernmentagency monitorcompliancewith labourlaws in <strong>the</strong><strong>for</strong>mal andin<strong>for</strong>maleconomyGovernmentimplementationef<strong>for</strong>tsE.g., In <strong>the</strong>instant caseto whatextent has <strong>the</strong>governmentdocumentedtenure rights of<strong>the</strong> poor?EffectivenessE.g., In <strong>the</strong>instant case,to what extentwas <strong>the</strong> poorperson ableto affect <strong>the</strong>registration?E.g., In <strong>the</strong>instant case,to what extentwas <strong>the</strong> poorperson ableto retainpossession of<strong>the</strong> property?E.g., to whatextent was <strong>the</strong>poor personw<strong>ork</strong>ing in<strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal or<strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>maleconomyable to enjoy<strong>the</strong> benefitsof labourprotectionlaws?E.g., To what extentwas <strong>the</strong> poor personin <strong>the</strong> instant caseable to affect <strong>the</strong>registration of his/her business?E.g., To what extentwas <strong>the</strong> poor personin <strong>the</strong> instant caseaware of <strong>the</strong>ir legalrights?an easier grasp of what needs to be monitored.2. Make <strong>the</strong> use of qualitative ra<strong>the</strong>r than quantitativeapproaches in monitoring <strong>the</strong> system, as<strong>the</strong>y offer a more complete and nuanced set ofdata that are numeric and narrative.3. Engage implementing parties and beneficiariesin <strong>the</strong> draw up of <strong>the</strong> monitoring systems andmethodologies and acquire feedback. Thiswill simplify <strong>the</strong> process of tracking previouslyidentified indicators. Focus group discussions,w<strong>ork</strong>shops and o<strong>the</strong>r similar methods can beused to ensure participation.331


4. Customize <strong>the</strong> choice of monitoring methods to<strong>the</strong> needs and constraints of <strong>the</strong> implementingagencies.5. Delegate <strong>the</strong> monitoring process to an externalbody selected from civil society organisations,think tanks and advocacy groups, to ensuregreater independence, transparency and accountability.A possible framew<strong>ork</strong> <strong>for</strong> a demand-led assessmentof government implementation of <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor recommendations is shownin Table 5.12, which is based on <strong>the</strong> framew<strong>ork</strong> of<strong>the</strong> World Resources Institute’s Access InitiativeAssessment method. Each cell of <strong>the</strong> matrix hasbeen populated with an indicator to serve as anexample. Those undertaking <strong>the</strong> assessment canrank each metric based on research guidelines anddata collected. These assessments, when repeatedover time, will show whe<strong>the</strong>r and how well LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor recommendations arebeing implemented. 12Monitoring of re<strong>for</strong>ms will involve seeking answersto critical questions. Among <strong>the</strong> questions thatmay need to be posed are <strong>the</strong> following: Are <strong>the</strong>policy re<strong>for</strong>ms really being implemented? And if so,do <strong>the</strong>y really matter? If <strong>the</strong>y do make a difference,how important is it? What are <strong>the</strong> gender impacts?Taking into consideration <strong>the</strong> multiple dimensionsof policy re<strong>for</strong>ms, <strong>the</strong> pace of implementation willlikely be gradual. There may not even be conspicuousimpact in <strong>the</strong> short-term. There<strong>for</strong>e, in<strong>the</strong> monitoring of progress, it will be important toestablish process indicators, and to pursue monitoringactivities ei<strong>the</strong>r on a continuous or repetitivebasis. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> entire set of measuringactivities — data collection, analysis, and interpretation— will need to be based on <strong>the</strong> country’snational priorities.6. Strategy and TacticsWe have reviewed <strong>the</strong> social, political and technicalfactors that stand in <strong>the</strong> way of poor people’slegal empowerment, and set <strong>for</strong>th broad ideasabout how to counter those <strong>for</strong>ces. Change agentsmust put aside preconceived or uni<strong>for</strong>m approachesto Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor to thinkcreatively about how to make Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor available, af<strong>for</strong>dable and acceptablein <strong>the</strong>ir own specific context. They must be on <strong>the</strong>look out <strong>for</strong> unintended consequences, perverseincentives, and hidden agendas. Their initiativesmust be in<strong>for</strong>med by pilot projects that can beamended if <strong>the</strong>y fail, and scaled-up and replicatedif <strong>the</strong>y w<strong>ork</strong>.In designing empowerment policies and decidingupon how to implement <strong>the</strong>m, change agents mustalways keep <strong>the</strong> following core values front andcentre:• Poverty reduction is <strong>the</strong> ultimate objective ofLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor, so every re<strong>for</strong>mmust be judged by <strong>the</strong> extent to which it impartsfreedom and allows poor people to gain morecontrol over <strong>the</strong>ir futures and to improve <strong>the</strong>irwell-being.• The peaceful struggle against impoverishmentmust be participatory, based on respect <strong>for</strong> humanrights, and with poor people playing activeroles along <strong>the</strong> way.• The gains of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poorshould be broad-based and take into account <strong>the</strong>diversity of disadvantaged groups, in particular,<strong>the</strong> indigenous people who are often inadvertentlyoverlooked by policymakers.• The gains also must include women; <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e,ano<strong>the</strong>r standard against which to measure LegalEmpowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor policy is whe<strong>the</strong>r ittakes full account of gender-specific effects.332


Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> poor in <strong>the</strong> end means socialtrans<strong>for</strong>mation — not only a more just distributionof wealth and income, but a more expansivesharing of power so disadvantaged people canbegin bringing about significant change through<strong>the</strong>ir own actions.Strategic FindingsAmong <strong>the</strong> strategic options and considerationsimplied in Chapters 1 through 4 of thisvolume, a number of <strong>the</strong>m stand out, and <strong>the</strong>y arementioned below. Several are rich with paradox,and government officials, civil society members,and development practitioners need to sort out <strong>the</strong>conflicting elements to determine <strong>the</strong> most promisingstrategic direction to take <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir community,country or region.1.Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor is easiest toimplement where it is needed least. An effectiveadministrative state, a set of transparentand accountable political institutions, and agrowing economy are predictors of success <strong>for</strong>legal empowerment policies. Yet, countries thatmeet <strong>the</strong>se criteria probably have <strong>the</strong>ir povertyand social exclusion under relative control; <strong>the</strong>bulk of <strong>the</strong> global poverty problem is in preciselythose nations that lack <strong>the</strong>se positive attributes,so implementation of Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor must usually be completed under inauspiciousconditions.2.There is a rich base of comparative internationalexperience, but no ready-made <strong>for</strong>mulas <strong>for</strong>legal empowerment. Solutions that suit one contextmay be dead wrong in ano<strong>the</strong>r. Greatcare should be taken to develop interventionsthat are appropriate <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> specific historical,socio-economic and political context of a givencountry.3.Think systemically, act incrementally. A nation’slegal and administrative setup functions likean ecosystem with a heavy measure of interdependence.That implies empowerment takessystemic changes. Yet, big bang approaches arerare and <strong>the</strong>y often run out of steam when <strong>the</strong>yare tried. In particular, any attempt to supplantand replace existing in<strong>for</strong>mal mechanisms seemsdoomed to failure. Instead, in<strong>for</strong>mal mechanismsmust be gradually integrated with <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mal.4.Think long, go short. Justice, labour and landissues are complicated and do not lend <strong>the</strong>mselvesreadily to a traditional two-year project approach.Yet, re<strong>for</strong>mers can never lose sight of <strong>the</strong>fact that politicians are in office <strong>for</strong> finite terms.The implementation process, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, needs toinvolve actors who are less affected by elections,and deliver successes on a regular basis. Evenif <strong>the</strong>se successes are small, <strong>the</strong>y must providetangible improvements to maintain <strong>the</strong> momentum<strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m.5.Start from afar, but change from within. Legalempowerment is on <strong>the</strong> international community’sagenda, as <strong>the</strong> very existence of this Commissionproves. Yet, pro-poor policy change hasto be endogenous. Any perception that <strong>for</strong>eigndonors drive re<strong>for</strong>m may prove counter-productive.Re<strong>for</strong>ms that do not find champions andbuild constituencies within are likely to fail (as<strong>the</strong>y should).6. Support associations of <strong>the</strong> poor, but do not compromise<strong>the</strong>ir independence. Capacity-developingsupport is important to associations of <strong>the</strong> poor,be <strong>the</strong>y small farmers’ cooperatives, communitybasedorganisations, domestic w<strong>ork</strong>er trade unionsor urban user-groups. The incongruity is thatassisting <strong>the</strong>se groups may cause <strong>the</strong>m to becomemore accountable to <strong>the</strong> external funding agencythan to <strong>the</strong>ir membership.7.W<strong>ork</strong> from <strong>the</strong> bottom up and <strong>the</strong> top down.Donor expectations regarding <strong>the</strong> interest of<strong>the</strong> poor in legal empowerment are often out333


of touch with <strong>the</strong> desires of <strong>the</strong> poor to get <strong>the</strong>state to provide services and benefits throughrecourse to client connections if necessary. At<strong>the</strong> same time, external change agents cannotignore <strong>the</strong> preconceptions and policy positions of<strong>the</strong> international agencies that are funding <strong>the</strong>irw<strong>ork</strong> with Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. Theyneed to think about how to balance <strong>the</strong>se twoperspectives.8.Decentralise…except when it is better to centralise.A common <strong>the</strong>me in several W<strong>ork</strong>ingGroup reports is <strong>the</strong> need to decentralise responsibility,resources and accountability <strong>for</strong> legalservice delivery to <strong>the</strong> lowest level at which <strong>the</strong>ycan be effectively managed. But decentralisationalso gives power to local elites opposed to <strong>the</strong>Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor agenda, so thisoption bears watching.9.Balance demand <strong>for</strong> change with <strong>the</strong> capacity toaccommodate change. The energy of <strong>the</strong> poor topinpoint solutions to <strong>the</strong>ir problems, to organise,and to engage in advocacy must be met withan equally receptive state. It is important togive attention to official capacity to respond to<strong>the</strong> thrust <strong>for</strong> change coming upwards from <strong>the</strong>grassroots.10. Put toge<strong>the</strong>r in<strong>for</strong>mal and <strong>for</strong>mal institutions.In<strong>for</strong>mal institutions and authority can be ofgreat utility in pursuing Legal Empowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor, but so can official institutions. Policymakersneed to combine <strong>the</strong> best features ofboth to facilitate implementation.11. Look <strong>for</strong> cooperation, but anticipate confrontation.There are Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor policies where all sides can benefit, <strong>for</strong>instance land readjustment which takes irregularlysub-divided land and reallocates it<strong>for</strong> public and private use according to planningrequirements. However, practitioners alsoneed to face up to <strong>the</strong> fact that compromiseand mutual adjustment are not always going tohappen with Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor.The narrow technical and legal aspects may be<strong>the</strong> least controversial, but even those ultimatelyaffect <strong>the</strong> distribution of power withinsociety. Governments trying to implement anempowerment agenda have to figure out waysei<strong>the</strong>r to reimburse or to defuse those possiblydisadvantaged by <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms. Managingpolitical risk throughout <strong>the</strong> implementationprocess, <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e, is critical.Tactical IdeasWhile walking <strong>the</strong> tightrope of <strong>the</strong>se strategicissues, change agents will also need to considerimplementation tactics. A list of common modesof action is presented below. These actions havebeen selected from materials put <strong>for</strong>ward by all <strong>the</strong>w<strong>ork</strong>ing groups involved in <strong>the</strong> preparation of thisvolume, and are presented in no particular order.1.Be opportunistic. Take tactical advantageof opportunities as <strong>the</strong>y arise and do not beconstrained by a programmemed calendar ofdeliverables.2.Use plain and local language. One of <strong>the</strong> keyelements <strong>for</strong> national ownership is language:dialogue, debate and in<strong>for</strong>mation sharing mustbe conducted in local languages; legal documentsshould be demystified by rendering <strong>the</strong>min layperson’s terms.3.W<strong>ork</strong> with para-professionals. A proposal raisedin several w<strong>ork</strong>ing group reports is to create anew generation of para-professionals, who aretrained and possibly certified to respond to <strong>the</strong>day-to-day service requirements of <strong>the</strong> poor, butwho do not require <strong>the</strong> advanced studies of currentprofessionals, which are often inappropriatelyscheduled, expensive and include subjects oflimited relevance <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> prospective client base.334


4.Bring existing technical solutions up to date.Particularly in <strong>the</strong> land sector, many of <strong>the</strong>existing legal instruments are inadequate. Landin<strong>for</strong>mation systems are often expensive, complicated,and bureaucratic and, as a result, quicklybecome outdated. Un<strong>for</strong>tunately, <strong>the</strong> systemsrequired, <strong>for</strong> example, to integrate innovative<strong>for</strong>ms of tenure (certificates, group rights, etc.)into <strong>the</strong> national spatial data infrastructure donot currently exist. As emphasised in Chapter 2of this report, <strong>the</strong> choice of long-term technicalsolutions must be driven by <strong>the</strong> willingness andability of <strong>the</strong> users to pay. Thus an importantelement in successful Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong>Poor implementation will be <strong>the</strong> appropriatenessof <strong>the</strong> underlying analysis and <strong>the</strong> existence orcreation of technical systems to support re<strong>for</strong>m.5.Bring toge<strong>the</strong>r technical expertise and grassrootsexperience. Technocrats dominate policymakingin Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor. While validreasons exist <strong>for</strong> some technical requirements,grassroots realities and community solutionsalso need to be understood and incorporated in<strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m process. If a law does not meet itsusers’ needs, it is useless to <strong>the</strong> poor.6.Dedicate resources to support participatoryprocesses and coordination. While technicalsolutions often attract significant donor andgovernment interest, capacity development <strong>for</strong>participation and coordination mechanisms isoften undervalued and <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e under-funded.O<strong>the</strong>r kinds of support, <strong>for</strong> example, are translationof laws and regulations into local languages,or grants to local civil society groups to lay bareLegal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor issues and tofund dissemination campaigns. Specific supportis required <strong>for</strong> coordination, preparation of researchand options papers, and in<strong>for</strong>mation dissemination.Peer exchanges (both inter-regionaland intra-regional) are ano<strong>the</strong>r valuable pro-poortool <strong>for</strong> building commitment to re<strong>for</strong>m and <strong>for</strong>maintaining momentum over time.7.Provide effective outreach. Under intense pressuresto deliver, in<strong>for</strong>mation and communicationprogrammemes are often neglected during implementation.Yet without a dedicated outreachcampaign, clients will rarely adopt <strong>the</strong> proposedre<strong>for</strong>ms. Feedback received from those involvedneeds to be cycled back into <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>m process,to keep it homegrown and responsive to demand.8.Provide access to in<strong>for</strong>mation. Two-way communicationbetween governments and <strong>the</strong> poorwill need to be improved. For example, access toin<strong>for</strong>mation has helped people to secure tenureand to tackle job discrimination through a betterunderstanding of <strong>the</strong>ir rights. There are also examplesin post-disaster and post-conflict nationsof <strong>the</strong> importance of providing access to in<strong>for</strong>mation.Mobilising resources to take advantage ofin<strong>for</strong>mation in support of Legal Empowerment of<strong>the</strong> Poor presents a challenge because in manycountries in<strong>for</strong>mation that is nominally ‘public’is in practice difficult to obtain. In India, <strong>for</strong> example,civil society organisations waged a fiercecampaign to gain access to public budget andexpenditure data using freedom of in<strong>for</strong>mationlaws in six states, which later culminated in <strong>the</strong>passage of a national law. However, in countrieswhere civil society is weak, and where certainsocial groups have been marginalized over extendedperiods of time, <strong>the</strong> ability of <strong>the</strong> poor toengage in effective collective action is likely tobe limited and fragile.9.Bundle service delivery. The strategy of bundlingservices is highlighted in several chapters of thisreport; it is seen as a cost-effective strategy <strong>for</strong>delivering a variety of services to <strong>the</strong> poor. Anexample is to deliver identity cards with vaccinationprogrammemes. Such bundling may alsohave <strong>the</strong> great potential of contributing to com-335


munity empowerment, especially if <strong>the</strong> deliveryis structured so as to rein<strong>for</strong>ce transparencyand accountability in community institutions.Experience with delivering bundled municipalservices (e.g., licensing, registration, tax and feepayments) through one-stop shops offers relevantlessons of utility <strong>for</strong> Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor re<strong>for</strong>ms as well. Membership-basedorganisations such as cooperatives, business associations,trade unions and grass-roots women’sorganisations can offer free or low-cost legalservices to <strong>the</strong> members.<strong>the</strong>se suggestions <strong>for</strong> strategy and tactics, remainingtrue to <strong>the</strong> core values of <strong>the</strong> legal empowermentagenda. Where <strong>the</strong>ir ef<strong>for</strong>ts prove successful,<strong>the</strong>y will make it possible <strong>for</strong> many more peoplenow mired in poverty to improve <strong>the</strong>ir lot in lifewithin <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>eseeable future. While implementationsuccess cannot be guaranteed because of <strong>the</strong>many countervailing factors mentioned earlier,steady, modest progress in fighting poverty withlegal tools and rights is well within <strong>the</strong> realm ofpossibility in most countries.10. Support alternative dispute resolution. All fourw<strong>ork</strong>ing groups emphasise <strong>the</strong> need to supportalternative dispute resolution mechanisms,including arbitration, mediation and conciliation.The fundamental challenge is to avoid <strong>the</strong>cost and expense of <strong>for</strong>mal litigation in return<strong>for</strong> decisions that are made transparently andcan be en<strong>for</strong>ced. Lessons learned from labourcourts may be instructive in o<strong>the</strong>r fields aswell.11. Collaborate with professional organisations.Professional organisations are promisingpotential allies. While lawyers, national barassociations, law re<strong>for</strong>m commissions, andlaw schools are oriented towards meeting <strong>the</strong>needs of <strong>the</strong> middle and upper classes, <strong>the</strong>yare also often willing to lend <strong>the</strong>ir professionalexpertise to <strong>the</strong> needs of <strong>the</strong> poor. Landsurveyors, valuators, and notaries often act asgatekeepers of rules that are often divorcedfrom <strong>the</strong> realities of <strong>the</strong> urban poor or evenholdovers from <strong>the</strong> colonial era, but <strong>the</strong>y mayalso be amenable to reorienting <strong>the</strong>ir thinking.The role of urban planners and local authoritiesalso merits attention. It may be possibleto convert <strong>the</strong>se stakeholders from possibleopponents into allies <strong>for</strong> change.Change agents are invited to consider and <strong>the</strong>n try336


Annex 1: PolicyImplementation ToolsListed below are a variety of tools deemed useful<strong>for</strong> implementing policies that may help toadvance legal empowerment re<strong>for</strong>ms:Advocacy/lobbying: These are attempts to influence<strong>the</strong> outcomes of any policymaking system throughendorsements, publicity, discussions, etc.Best practices (collection and dissemination): Abest practice is a management idea that assumes<strong>the</strong>re is a technique, method, process, activity, incentiveor reward that is more effective at deliveringa particular outcome than any o<strong>the</strong>r technique,method or process. The idea is that with proper processes,checks, and testing, a desired outcome canbe delivered with lessproblems and fewer un<strong>for</strong>eseencomplications.Contextual analysis: This involves a system-widereview of economic, social, cultural, political, administrative,and institutional factors that affect <strong>the</strong>ease of implementing a particular public policy in acountry, such as legal empowerment re<strong>for</strong>ms.Community Mapping: A Community Map is a visualrepresentation of what <strong>the</strong> community perceives as itscommunity space. This includes showing <strong>the</strong> boundaryof <strong>the</strong> community as understood by communitymembers and all <strong>the</strong> elements recognised by <strong>the</strong>mas part of <strong>the</strong>ir area. Most of <strong>the</strong> spatial in<strong>for</strong>mationis obtained through direct observation. The communitymembers <strong>the</strong>mselves decide what does and doesnot go on <strong>the</strong> map. Some items of importance to <strong>the</strong>community may not be noticeable to outsiders, suchas sacred sites or clan boundaries (ICMM, <strong>the</strong> WorldBank and ESMAP 2005).Competencies Assessment: Measuring and recording<strong>the</strong> skills of an individual or group is an essentialstarting point <strong>for</strong> any Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor implementation strategy. Competenciesmay include knowledge, skills, and abilities as wellas o<strong>the</strong>r characteristics such as initiative, motivation,legitimacy and values. Competencies can beassessed in <strong>the</strong> framew<strong>ork</strong> of a facilitated w<strong>ork</strong>shopprocess or on an individual basis, <strong>for</strong> example.Conflict resolution: Conflict is a normal part of relationshipsand occurs whenever people or groupshave different expectations of joint or intersectingactivities. Instead of seeking to avoid conflict atall costs, which would be unrealistic, it is better tolearn to recognise and manage conflict as part ofgood relationship building and maintenance. Notall conflicts can be resolved, but methods exist <strong>for</strong>managing differences between stakeholders so thatdevelopment activities can continue (ICMM, <strong>the</strong>World Bank and ESMAP 2005).Domestic resource mobilisation: As defined in <strong>the</strong>Monterrey Consensus, domestic resource mobilisationincludes policies that foster good governancethat is responsive to <strong>the</strong> people’s needs; an appropriatepolicy and regulatory framew<strong>ork</strong>; <strong>the</strong> fightingof corruption at all levels; sound macroeconomicpolicies aimed at sustaining high growth rates, fullemployment, stability and poverty eradication; fiscalsustainability; investment in basic economic andsocial infrastructure; improvement in w<strong>ork</strong>ing conditions;streng<strong>the</strong>ning and development of <strong>the</strong> domesticfinancial sector, enhanced by microfinanceand credit <strong>for</strong> micro- and small and medium-sizedenterprises, and <strong>the</strong> establishment of developmentbanks to fur<strong>the</strong>r facilitate access to credit.Exchanges: Practitioners may visit or temporarilyw<strong>ork</strong> in a similar organisation or job assignment ina <strong>for</strong>eign country to gain practical and comparativeexperience about a policy such as legal empowerment.Focus groups: These are groups selected <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir337


elevance to a particular area of investigation, whichare engaged by a trained facilitator in discussionsdesigned to share insights, ideas, and observationson <strong>the</strong> area of concern. Focus groups are typicallyopen-ended, discursive, and used to gain a deeperunderstanding of respondents’ attitudes and opinions.A key feature is that participants are ableinteract with each o<strong>the</strong>r. The group dynamic oftenprovides richer insights and data than would havebeen achieved by interviewing <strong>the</strong> participants individually(ICMM, <strong>the</strong> World Bank and ESMAP 2005)Force field analysis: Force field analysis helps clarifya group’s position on a particular policy. It is agraphical representation in which groups are placedon a continuum from ‘oppose’ to ‘favour’, where <strong>the</strong>middle of <strong>the</strong> continuum is ‘neutral’. It is useful inproviding a quick overview of sources of major oppositionand support (Brinkerhoff and Crosby 2002).Fundraising: There are individuals, corporations,foundations, and national and international governmentbodies that may be approached <strong>for</strong> help infunding Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor.Gender audit: A participatory and self-assessmentapproach to promote organisational learning aboutgender mainstreaming (Moser 2005).Impact evaluation: An impact evaluation assesseschanges in <strong>the</strong> well-being of individuals, households,communities or firms that can be attributedto a particular project, programmeme or policy. Itis aimed at providing feedback to help improve <strong>the</strong>design of programmemes and policies. In additionto providing <strong>for</strong> improved accountability, impactevaluations are useful <strong>for</strong> dynamic learning, allowingpolicymakers to improve ongoing programmemesand ultimately better allocate funds acrossprogrammemes.Influence mapping: This technique identifies <strong>the</strong>individuals and groups with <strong>the</strong> power to effect akey decision. It fur<strong>the</strong>r investigates <strong>the</strong> positionand motives of each player and <strong>the</strong> best channelsthrough which to communicate with <strong>the</strong>m (Start andHovland 2004).Institutional Analysis: Institutional analysis studies<strong>the</strong> institutional set-up in and around a givencommunity, including how important each institutionis, how <strong>the</strong>y interact with each o<strong>the</strong>r and whoparticipates in <strong>the</strong>m. This in<strong>for</strong>mation can be ga<strong>the</strong>redthrough an interview process, <strong>for</strong> example, byasking community members to describe <strong>the</strong> institutionspresent in <strong>the</strong>ir community, <strong>the</strong>ir function,importance in relation to o<strong>the</strong>r institutions, and ifand how <strong>the</strong>y participate in <strong>the</strong>m. Institutional analysisis particularly useful in identifying institutionsat <strong>the</strong> community level that can play an importantrole in <strong>the</strong> legal empowerment process (ICMM, <strong>the</strong>World Bank and ESMAP 2005).Institutional twinning: Institutional twinning is a<strong>for</strong>m of staff exchange. For instance, staff of a particularagency would visit a similar institution in a<strong>for</strong>eign country, with <strong>the</strong> aim of exchanging expertise.Often <strong>the</strong> exchange is two-way (Ouchi 2004).Internship programmemes: These are programmemesthat integrate study with planned and supervisedcareer-related w<strong>ork</strong> experience on practicalissues of implementation.Logical framew<strong>ork</strong> approach: LFA is an analytical,presentational and management tool that canhelp planners and managers to analyse <strong>the</strong> existingsituation during project preparation, establish alogical hierarchy of means by which objectives willbe reached, identify some of <strong>the</strong> potential risks, establishhow outputs and outcomes might best bemonitored and evaluated, and present a summary of<strong>the</strong> project in a standard <strong>for</strong>mat (Örtengren 2004).LFA is an overarching tool that may use o<strong>the</strong>r techniqueslisted here, <strong>for</strong> instance situational analysisand stakeholder analysis.338


MIS: A Management In<strong>for</strong>mation System is one offour components that establish an efficient policymonitoring system (see Section 5). MIS is used tocollect, analyse, store, and disseminate in<strong>for</strong>mationuseful <strong>for</strong> decision-making in a project. It trackstargeted indicators that help in<strong>for</strong>m choices in aproject. Design of <strong>the</strong> MIS should be based on <strong>the</strong>principles of adaptation to user needs, and availabilityof resources, user participation, parsimony,and simplicity. It is important to understand fullywhat needs to be monitored.National symposium: This is a high-profile way topublicise Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor or o<strong>the</strong>rpolicies.Opportunity Ranking: This is used to help communitymembers and development partners decideupon which projects to start implementing. Takingaccount of locally available resources, skills, andcapacities, it is built around a scoring system thatranks various options against agreed criteria.Outreach: Methods <strong>for</strong> publicizing Legal Empowermentof <strong>the</strong> Poor or o<strong>the</strong>r policies include mediacampaigns, school programmemes, public speakingengagements, publications, public hearings, studycircles. (Study circles, <strong>for</strong> example, are a method ofadult education and social change popular in Scandinavia._Para-professionals: These are people in variousoccupational fields, such as education, healthcare,and law, who have obtained a certificate by passingan exam that enables <strong>the</strong>m to per<strong>for</strong>m a task requiringsignificant knowledge, but without having <strong>the</strong>occupational license to per<strong>for</strong>m at <strong>the</strong> professionallevel in <strong>the</strong> field.Participatory budgeting: Participatory budgeting isa process of democratic deliberation and decisionmaking,in which ordinary residents decide how toallocate part of a municipal or public budget. Participatorybudgeting is usually characterised by severalbasic design features: identification of spendingpriorities by community members, election ofbudget delegates to represent different communities,facilitation and technical assistance by publicemployees, local and higher level assemblies todeliberate and vote on spending priorities, and <strong>the</strong>implementation of local direct-impact communityprojects. Various studies have suggested that participatorybudgeting results in more equitable publicspending, higher quality of life, increased satisfactionof basic needs, greater government transparencyand accountability, increased levels of publicparticipation (especially by marginalised residents),and democratic and citizenship learning.Participatory Poverty Assessments: A PPA is a toolthat allows consultation of <strong>the</strong> poor directly. Findingsare transmitted to policymakers, <strong>the</strong>reby enabling<strong>the</strong> poor to influence policy. APPA uses a variety offlexible participatory methods that combine visualtechniques (mapping, matrices, diagrams) and verbaltechniques (open-ended interviews, discussiongroups). It also emphasises exercises that facilitatein<strong>for</strong>mation sharing, analysis, and action. The goalis to give <strong>the</strong> intended beneficiaries more controlover <strong>the</strong> research process. To ensure follow-up at<strong>the</strong> community level (a principle of participatory research),many PPAs have involved <strong>the</strong> developmentof community action plans subsequently supportedby local governments or NGOs (Robb, 2000).Plain language: In many countries, <strong>the</strong> law is onlydrafted and administrated in <strong>the</strong> national language,which many of <strong>the</strong> poor may not speak or read.Translation of laws into local language is hence anobvious way of improving access of <strong>the</strong> poor to in<strong>for</strong>mation.This may also involve rendering legal jargoninto everyday terms in <strong>the</strong> dominant country language.Policy briefings: These are summary reports that re-339


view <strong>the</strong> current state of practice and methodologiesand summarize critical issues and implications.Policy characteristics analysis: This analysis in<strong>for</strong>ms<strong>the</strong> understanding of <strong>the</strong> re<strong>for</strong>mers, on <strong>the</strong>dimensions and dynamics of <strong>the</strong> policy, its originsand where greatest support and opposition are mostlikely to lie. Its purpose is to provide a systematicunderstanding of <strong>the</strong> policy that can carry over intomore detailed appraisal such as <strong>the</strong> political mappingor <strong>the</strong> stakeholder analysis. It is designed toanswer questions such as <strong>the</strong> exact aim of <strong>the</strong> policy,its implementation context, how <strong>the</strong> public mayreact to change, how consequential <strong>the</strong> change willbe (Brinkerhoff and Crosby 2002).Political mapping: Political Mapping is a means<strong>for</strong> organising in<strong>for</strong>mation about <strong>the</strong> political landscapein an illustrative way. Macro-political mappingprovides analysis of political alliances at <strong>the</strong>macro (national or sector) level, while micro-politicalmapping provides more disaggregated insightsinto <strong>the</strong> political landscape. Political mapping canbe used to illustrate concentrations of support <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> government.Problem Census: The Problem Census is usuallyconducted in a small group setting, at <strong>the</strong> localcommunity level, <strong>for</strong> example. Designed as a nonthreatening,focused discussion that uses smallgroup dynamics, its objective is to elicit a comprehensiveand ranked census of <strong>the</strong> problems, real orperceived, of households and <strong>the</strong> community as awhole as well as <strong>the</strong> community’s proposed solutions.This approach gives community members <strong>the</strong>opportunity to articulate and prioritise <strong>the</strong> problems<strong>the</strong>y consider need addressing in <strong>the</strong>ir community,to discuss <strong>the</strong>m as a group, and <strong>the</strong>n collectively decideon which problems to solve (ICMM, <strong>the</strong> WorldBank and ESMAP 2005).Problem solving studies: Problem solving studiesare aimed at devising tailored and practical solutionsto implementation issues. As <strong>for</strong> MIS above,<strong>the</strong> design of problem-solving studies should bebased on <strong>the</strong> principles of adaptation to user needs,and availability of resources, user participation, parsimony,and simplicity. (Also see Section 5.)Problem tree: Problem-tree analysis serves toidentify immediate and direct causes and effects ofa focal problem assisted by graphic representation.The technique helps illustrate context and interrelationshipof problems as well as possible impactswhen targeting projects and programmemes towardsspecific issues.Social Baseline Study: A base line study consistsof collecting and analysing baseline data that describes<strong>the</strong> social and economic environment of anarea of interest as well as <strong>the</strong> characteristics of atarget group. A social baseline study, <strong>for</strong> example,would observer demographic factors (population,population density, age, ethnicity, health, income,etc.), socio-economic determinants (e.g. factors affectingincome and productivity, land tenure, accessto productive inputs and markets, family composition,access to wage opportunities), social organisation(e.g. participation in local-level institutionsand decision-making processes, access to servicesand in<strong>for</strong>mation), economic organisation (e.g. localand regional businesses and commercial structures,infrastructure supporting economic activity, government,and o<strong>the</strong>r economic/industrial developmentplans <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> area), socio-political context (stakeholderorganisations, development goals, priorities,commitment to development objectives, controlover resources, experience, and relationship witho<strong>the</strong>r stakeholder groups), historical context (e.g.historical issues and events, migration, relocation),needs and values (stakeholder attitudes and valuesdetermining whe<strong>the</strong>r development interventionsare needed and wanted, appropriate incentives <strong>for</strong>change, and capacity of stakeholders to manage <strong>the</strong>process of change), human rights context (prevail-340


ing human rights issues and country risks), institutions(role, governance, resources, capacities oflocal institutions as well as regulatory framew<strong>ork</strong>),cultural background (cultural norms and practicesand places of high cultural value) (ICMM, <strong>the</strong> WorldBank and ESMAP 2005).Social Impact and Opportunities Assessment: Thisis a process that identifies negative and positive impactsresulting from a given project. It <strong>the</strong>n looksat ways of maximising opportunities that can arisefrom <strong>the</strong> positive impacts and offsetting or minimising<strong>the</strong> negative effects. Being able to demonstratepositive effects at <strong>the</strong> early stages of a project facilitateslocal engagement and participation (ICMM,<strong>the</strong> World Bank and ESMAP 2005).Stakeholder analysis: Stakeholder analysis is designedto identify those interests that should betaken into account when making a decision. It assesses<strong>the</strong> nature of a policy’s constituents, <strong>the</strong>irexpectations, interests, intensity of <strong>the</strong>ir interest in<strong>the</strong> issue at hand, and <strong>the</strong> resources <strong>the</strong>y can bringto bear on <strong>the</strong> outcome of <strong>the</strong> policy. It helps ensurethat <strong>the</strong> policies are designed in ways that improve<strong>the</strong>ir chances of adoption and implementation. Inimplementation, it helps build an understanding of<strong>the</strong> relative importance of various groups and <strong>the</strong>role <strong>the</strong>y might play. To be useful, it is importantthat <strong>the</strong> stakeholder analysis indicates why interestsshould be taken into account (Brinkerhoff andCrosby 2002).Stakeholder monitoring (household surveys, keyin<strong>for</strong>mant interviews): Household surveys providedata on spending <strong>for</strong> different kinds of goods as wellas household characteristics, such as age, gender,education and occupation of family members. Dataobtained from household surveys is particularly useful<strong>for</strong> measuring income poverty and relating it tohousehold characteristics. They are <strong>the</strong> most valuableresource available <strong>for</strong> assessing economic outcomes,as well as some aspects of opportunity, and<strong>for</strong> understanding how those outcomes are associatedwith household characteristics (Stern, Dethierand Rogers 2005). A key in<strong>for</strong>mant interview is a<strong>for</strong>m of in-depth interview often used in <strong>the</strong> initialphase of a project and again in evaluation. Key in<strong>for</strong>mantsare selected <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir first-hand knowledgeabout <strong>the</strong> topic of interest. Some of <strong>the</strong> people whomight be approached in a key-in<strong>for</strong>mant interviewinclude a community leader, <strong>the</strong> head of an NGOthat could become a partner, or <strong>the</strong> leader of a smallbusiness organisation. (See Section 5 of this chapter<strong>for</strong> fur<strong>the</strong>r discussion.)Strategic Planning Framew<strong>ork</strong>/SWOT/PEST: Strategicplanning is a general management techniqueof defining development objectives, planning toachieve those objectives, and deciding how to knowwhen you have succeeded. Strategic planning beginsinternally, and as it progresses toward detailed activityplanning, it needs to be shared and reviewed bystakeholders. SWOT Analysis stands <strong>for</strong> ‘Strengths,Weaknesses, Opportunities, and Threats’ and is aspecific strategic planning tool used to evaluatethose involved in a project or in a business venture.It involves specifying <strong>the</strong> objective of <strong>the</strong> projectand identifying <strong>the</strong> internal and external factorsthat are favourable and unfavourable to achievingthat objective. PEST analysis stands <strong>for</strong> ‘Political,Economic, Social, and Technological analysis,’ anddescribes a framew<strong>ork</strong> of macro environmental factorsused in environmental scanning. It is a part of<strong>the</strong> external analysis when doing strategic planningand gives a certain overview of <strong>the</strong> different macroenvironmental factors that <strong>the</strong> company has to takeinto consideration.Technical assistance: Technical assistance meanstransfer of new knowledge along with new technologyto o<strong>the</strong>rs who do not know about it. The field of technicalassistance may include management, operationssystems, engineering and o<strong>the</strong>r technologies.341


Training (on leadership, group w<strong>ork</strong> and relatedmanagement issues): This tool covers a variety ofplanned, prepared, and coordinated programmemesto give group leaders and practitioners in<strong>for</strong>mation<strong>the</strong>y can use to per<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong>ir jobs better.Travel grants/internships <strong>for</strong> officials: These allowmid-career professionals and para-professionals toacquire practical knowledge by visiting or serving inorganisations in <strong>for</strong>eign countries.Web-based support: The Internet is an invaluabletool <strong>for</strong> disseminating in<strong>for</strong>mation to change agentsand development practitioners about legal empowermentof <strong>the</strong> poor.W<strong>ork</strong>shops: These are structured group meetingsat which a variety of key stakeholder groups,whose activities or influence affect a developmentissue or project, share knowledge and w<strong>ork</strong> towarda common vision. With <strong>the</strong> help of a w<strong>ork</strong>shop facilitator,participants undertake a series of activitiesdesigned to help <strong>the</strong>m progress toward <strong>the</strong> developmentobjective (consensus building, in<strong>for</strong>mationsharing, prioritisation of objectives, team building,and so on). Stakeholder w<strong>ork</strong>shops are used to initiate,establish, and sustain collaboration in policiessuch as Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor (WorldBank 1996).Annex 2: Existing Toolkits:An InventoryAccess to justiceThere are several access-to-justice toolkits, focusingon different aspects of <strong>the</strong> justice question. Among<strong>the</strong> major ones are <strong>the</strong> following:• The Access Initiative Assessment (TAI) Toolkit. 13Although this has been designed with <strong>the</strong> environmentin mind, <strong>the</strong> concepts are capable ofbeing extended to more general access to justiceissues. There are four categories in <strong>the</strong> TAI toolkit— access to in<strong>for</strong>mation, public participation, accessto justice, and capacity development. Moreimportantly, <strong>the</strong> indicators are divided into law,ef<strong>for</strong>t and effectiveness. <strong>Law</strong> indicators measure<strong>the</strong> presence and scope of <strong>the</strong> law, its breadthand support <strong>for</strong> access and whe<strong>the</strong>r it providessufficient guidance <strong>for</strong> implementation and en<strong>for</strong>cement.Ef<strong>for</strong>t indicators assess governmentaction taken to provide access, including actionto implement laws. Effectiveness indicators assesswhe<strong>the</strong>r laws and government ef<strong>for</strong>ts haveresulted in effective access and whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>world has changed because of <strong>the</strong> level of accessachieved. Given <strong>the</strong> focus of legal empowerment,adapted use of <strong>the</strong> access to justice indicators (onall three counts of law, ef<strong>for</strong>t and effectiveness)seems to be <strong>the</strong> most appropriate.• The Office on Drugs and Crime of <strong>the</strong> United Nations(UNODC) has a Criminal Justice AssessmentToolkit 14 This has separate segments on policing,access to justice, custodial and non-custodialmeasures and cross-cutting issues. Given <strong>the</strong>focus of legal empowerment, adapted use of <strong>the</strong>access to justice indicators (covering four headsof <strong>the</strong> courts; <strong>the</strong> independence, impartiality andintegrity of <strong>the</strong> judiciary; <strong>the</strong> prosecution service;and legal defence and legal aid) seems to be <strong>the</strong>342


most appropriate.• Although not quite presented as a toolkit, UNDP’sPractitioner’s Guide on Access to Justice can beinterpreted as a toolkit 15 This has <strong>the</strong> additionaladvantage of bringing in a pro-poor angle. ‘Themeaning of access to justice is interpretativeand contextual. When people think of ‘access tojustice’, <strong>the</strong>y are not necessarily thinking of <strong>the</strong>justice system. For example, a UNDP participatorysurvey on people’s perceptions of justice inIndia found that slum dwellers prioritised accessto justice with regard to economic issues, whereasmembers of marginalised castes highlighted<strong>the</strong> social dimensions of access, and indigenousminorities highlighted <strong>the</strong> political dimension.There<strong>for</strong>e, <strong>the</strong> potential of <strong>for</strong>mal and in<strong>for</strong>malmechanisms to provide people with a sense of‘justice’ in a particular situation depends on <strong>the</strong>context, and is just one part of a bigger picture.’• The Asian Development Bank has a few toolkits in<strong>the</strong> general law area, but <strong>the</strong> most relevant one is<strong>the</strong> one on gender, law and policy 16 .Property rightsToolkits on property rights belong to different categoriesor segments — such as housing, land rights,minerals, <strong>for</strong>ests and intellectual property. Among<strong>the</strong> major ones are <strong>the</strong> following:• The Housing and Land Rights Netw<strong>ork</strong> (HLRN) of<strong>the</strong> Habitat International Coalition (HIC) has a toolkit<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> ‘housing rights defender’ 17 — ‘At <strong>the</strong>end of <strong>the</strong> last century, close to 1.2 billion peopleof <strong>the</strong> world survived in housing conditions thatwere unhealthy and precarious, including 100 millionwho were homeless. At least 600 million urbanresidents in developing countries, with <strong>the</strong>senumbers swelling everyday, already live in housingof such poor quality and with such inadequate provisionof water, sanitation and drainage that <strong>the</strong>irlives and health are under continuous threat.’• USAID has a toolkit <strong>for</strong> situations where <strong>the</strong>re isa link between land rights (or <strong>the</strong>ir lack) and conflict18 Today a ‘menu’ of approaches helps facilitatebroader access to land and engenders greaterequality in economic opportunity. In <strong>the</strong> past,land was typically taken from large landholdersand redistributed to <strong>the</strong> ‘land-needy’ by way ofexpropriation, usually with compensation or channelledthrough land funds. Increasingly, marketmediatedand community-managed ef<strong>for</strong>ts arebeing explored, including land rental market facilitation.There is a parallel USAID toolkit on <strong>the</strong>relationship between minerals and conflict 19 andyet ano<strong>the</strong>r one on <strong>for</strong>ests and conflict. 20Labour rights• Core Labour Standards Handbook, co-publishedby ADB (Asian Development Bank) and ILO. 21• The Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory Facilityof <strong>the</strong> World Bank group has a toolkit specificallyon <strong>the</strong> issue of how private participation in infrastructurecan affect <strong>the</strong> labour market, becauseof fears of job losses and changes in employmentstatus. 22 This is designed <strong>for</strong> policy-makers andpractitioners, especially in countries where <strong>the</strong>reis an absence of social safety nets.• The ADB has a toolkit, although it is described asa technical note, on labour issues in public sectorrestructuring. 23• ILO: Human Trafficking and Forced Labour Exploitation:Guidance <strong>for</strong> Legislation and <strong>Law</strong> En<strong>for</strong>cement.24• D. Tajgman has edited, Extending Labour <strong>Law</strong> toAll W<strong>ork</strong>ers: Promoting Decent W<strong>ork</strong> in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>malEconomy in Cambodia, Thailand and Mongolia(ILO, Bangkok, 2006).• Ojeda Avilés, Métodos y prácticas en la soluciónde conflictos laborales: Un estudio internacional(ILO, Geneva, Dialogue Document No. 13, May2007). [Methods and practices in <strong>the</strong> resolution343


of labour disputes: An international study]• In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy Resources Database, which includescase studies. 25• Labour legislation guidelines (which provide substantiveguidance on drafting legislation that iscompatible with core labour standards) features achapter covering elements to take into account inany legislative drafting process. 26• Child W<strong>ork</strong>ers in Asia/ILO (2006). Raising onevoice: Training manual <strong>for</strong> advocates of <strong>the</strong> rightsof child domestic w<strong>ork</strong>ers. 27• ILO’s Gender Mainstreaming Strategy (GEMS) andToolkit <strong>for</strong> Asia and <strong>the</strong> Pacific includes elementsthat can be applied to law re<strong>for</strong>m processes toensure <strong>the</strong>ir gender inclusivity. 28• ILO: Gender Equality and Decent W<strong>ork</strong> — SelectedILO Conventions and Recommendationspromoting Gender Equality. 29• The ILO Gender, Poverty and Employment (GPE)Programmeme has included law re<strong>for</strong>m as onemeans of tackling exclusion that keeps women inpoverty. Its capacity-building and policy developmenttools, used in countries in all regions, arecaptured in <strong>the</strong> GPE Package, which is available inEnglish and Spanish (Arabic <strong>for</strong>thcoming). 30• ILO: Sustainable Enterprises. (Report of <strong>the</strong> Director-General,International Labour Conference,96th Session, 2007), and <strong>the</strong> Conclusions onsustainable enterprises adopted at <strong>the</strong> Conference(Provisional Record No. 20), set out featuresof legislation promoting both sustainable entrepreneurshipand protection <strong>for</strong> labour rights.Belgium, Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands, India, Mexico, Hungary,Georgia, Kenya and Belarus. 31 Second, <strong>the</strong>re isa parallel and complementary toolkit on goodpractices <strong>for</strong> business inspections 32 that lists outbenchmarks that can be used as guidelines by re<strong>for</strong>mers.Third, <strong>the</strong>re is a guide on <strong>the</strong> design andimplementation of business registration re<strong>for</strong>msat <strong>the</strong> national level, with good-practice casesand examples of re<strong>for</strong>m from several countries. 33Fourth, <strong>the</strong>re is a toolkit <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> simplification ofbusiness regulations at <strong>the</strong> sub-regional level,with a focus on <strong>the</strong> municipal level. 34• The Commonwealth Secretariat has a CommonwealthYouth Credit Initiative Toolkit to help governments,development agencies and NGOs toimplement micro-credit programmemes. 35• A micro-credit rating toolkit was prepared by <strong>the</strong>UNDP’s regional centre in Colombo, based on micro-creditexperience in Bangladesh, India, Myanmar,Sri Lanka and Sudan. 36• The Office on Drugs and Crime of <strong>the</strong> United Nations(UNODC) has an anti-corruption toolkit, under<strong>the</strong> framew<strong>ork</strong> of <strong>the</strong> Global ProgrammemeAgainst Corruption (GPAC). 37• Transparency International has a range of corruption-fighters’toolkits <strong>for</strong> monitoring public institutionsand demanding and promoting accountableand responsive public administration. 38Business• Business licensing is often a major barrier to doingbusiness and over-regulation and red tape areassociated with low income, low productivity andlarge levels of in<strong>for</strong>mality and corruption. First,<strong>the</strong> World Bank group has a business licensingre<strong>for</strong>m toolkit, with eight case studies from344


Annex 3: Existing Indicatorsand Indices — An InventoryAccess to justice• Bertelsmann Trans<strong>for</strong>mation Index (BTI), withdata since 2004 <strong>for</strong> 119 developing countries.The status index (SI) of BTI has a question on ruleof law. 39• Business Environment Risk Intelligence’s OperationRisk Index (ORI) has data on 50 countriessince 1996, with a question on en<strong>for</strong>ceability ofcontracts. 40• Columbia University’s State Capacity Survey hasdata since 1999 on 108 countries and has aquestion on <strong>the</strong> degree to which ethno-culturaland/or religious conflict posed a threat to politicalstability in <strong>the</strong> country. 41• Columbia University’s State Capacity Survey hasdata since 1999 on 108 countries and has a questionon <strong>the</strong> state’s adherence to rule of law. 42• Since 1997, <strong>the</strong> Economist Intelligence Unit(EIU) maintains a database on <strong>the</strong> economicand business environment in approximately 120developed and developing countries. There aresix questions on violent crime, organised crime,fairness of <strong>the</strong> judicial process, en<strong>for</strong>ceability ofcontracts, speediness of <strong>the</strong> judicial process, andconfiscation/appropriation. 43• Freedom House has three separate rankings; buttwo — Nations in Transit and Countries at <strong>the</strong>Crossroads — are only applied to a limited numberof countries. The one that can be used readilyis Freedom in <strong>the</strong> World, in existence since 1978and currently with a database of 192 countries.There is a question in determining <strong>the</strong> ranking asto whe<strong>the</strong>r cultural, ethnic, religious and o<strong>the</strong>rminority groups have reasonable self-determination,self-government, autonomy and participation.There is a separate question on whe<strong>the</strong>rcitizens are equal under <strong>the</strong> law, with access toan independent, non-discriminatory judiciary. Yetano<strong>the</strong>r question can be included in this accessto justice head and this is about whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re arepersonal social freedoms, including gender equality,property rights, freedom of movement, choiceof residence and choice of marriage and size offamily. 44• Since 2004, Transparency International and Galluphave <strong>the</strong> Global Barometer Survey <strong>for</strong> 69 developedand developing countries. There are twoseparate questions on trust in <strong>the</strong> legal systemand concern with <strong>the</strong> level of crime. 45• Since 1996, Global Insight’s Global Risk Servicecovers 117 developed and developing countriesand has a question on losses and costs of crime. Italso has two separate questions on en<strong>for</strong>ceabilityof government contracts and private contracts. 46• Since 1996, Global Insight’s Business Conditionsand Risks Indicators cover 202 developed and developingcountries. This has two separate questionson judicial independence and crime. 47• Since 1995, Heritage Foundation and <strong>the</strong> WallStreet Journal produce an index of economic freedomthat covers 161 countries. This has a questionon <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> black market. 48• Since 1996, Institute <strong>for</strong> Management Developmentbrings out a World Competitiveness Yearbookthat has data on 49 developed and developingcountries. This has a question on whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>legal environment is detrimental to <strong>the</strong> country’scompetitiveness. There is also an additionalquestion on whe<strong>the</strong>r justice is fairly administeredin society. 49• Since 1982, Merchant International Group Limitedhas data <strong>for</strong> 155 developed and developing countries.This has a question on legal safeguards. 50• Since 1982, Political Risk Services produces dataon country risks. The financial and economic risk345


categories don’t interest us. But within <strong>the</strong> politicalrisk category (140 developing and developedcountries), <strong>the</strong>re is a law and order question,divided into two-subcomponents of law andorder. 51• The US State Department has a Trafficking inPeople Report, started in 2001 and covering 149developed and developing countries. 52• The Cingranelli-Richards Human Rights Datasetcovers 192 developed and developing countries.It has a question on independence of <strong>the</strong> judiciaryand ano<strong>the</strong>r one on imprisonments becauseof ethnicity, race, and political or religious beliefs.53• The World Bank’s World Business EnvironmentSurvey has existed since 1998 and covers 80developed and developing countries. This hasseveral questions on access to justice and ruleof law — predictability of changes in rules andlaws, quality of <strong>the</strong> police, organised crime, streetcrime, fair and impartial courts, af<strong>for</strong>dable courts,consistent/predictability of courts, en<strong>for</strong>cementof court decisions, dishonesty in courts and functioningof <strong>the</strong> judiciary. 54• Since 1996, <strong>the</strong> World Economic Forum hasbrought out <strong>the</strong> Global Competitiveness Reportand this covers 104 developed and developingcountries. This has questions on common crime,organised crime, money laundering (through banksand non-banks), quality of police, independenceof <strong>the</strong> judiciary, legal framew<strong>ork</strong> to challenge <strong>the</strong>legality of government action, settlements outside<strong>the</strong> court system, compliance with court rulingsand/or arbitration awards, en<strong>for</strong>cement of commercialcontracts and use of illegal means to adjudicatedisputes. 55• The World Bank’s World Development Indicatorsdatabase can be used <strong>for</strong> female w<strong>ork</strong> participationrates, unemployment among women and femalerepresentation in national parliament. Thisgives data on 184 countries. 56• Although developed <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> environment area, TheAccess Initiative’s (TAI) 148 indicators <strong>for</strong> 40countries can also be selectively used. 57 Theseindicators are divided under law, ef<strong>for</strong>t and effectiveness.One should probably concentrate onlaw indicators, ra<strong>the</strong>r than ef<strong>for</strong>t and effectiveness.The last two essentially belong to a tool-kitcategory. The law indicators are again divided intoaccess to in<strong>for</strong>mation, public participation andaccess to justice. We would propose applying <strong>the</strong>last heading, on access to justice, in which case,<strong>the</strong>re are 23 questions to consider. Questionslinked to free legal aid, government immunity,confidentiality of in<strong>for</strong>mation on government actionand independence of appellate bodies shouldcertainly be picked up.Property rights• Bertelsmann Trans<strong>for</strong>mation Index (BTI) has datasince 2004 <strong>for</strong> 119 developing countries. Thestatus index (SI) of BTI has a question on privateproperty. 58• The World Bank’s Country Policy and InstitutionalAssessment (CPIA) database has data on 136 developingcountries. The creation of <strong>the</strong> databasegoes back to <strong>the</strong> late 1970s. There is a questionon property rights. 59• Since 1997, Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU)has a database on <strong>the</strong> economic and businessenvironment in 120 developed and developingcountries. There are two separate questions onintellectual property rights protection and privateproperty protection. 60• Since 1996, Institute <strong>for</strong> Management Developmentbrings out a World CompetitivenessYearbook that has data on 49 developed anddeveloping countries. This has a question onwhe<strong>the</strong>r personal security and private propertyare adequately protected and a separate question346


on whe<strong>the</strong>r patent and copyright protection isadequately en<strong>for</strong>ced. 61• The World Bank’s World Business EnvironmentSurvey has existed since 1998 and covers 80developed and developing countries. This hastwo questions on confidence in <strong>the</strong> judicial systemin ensuring property rights and violation ofpatents. 62• Since 1996, World Economic Forum has broughtout <strong>the</strong> Global Competitiveness Report and thiscovers 104 developed and developing countries.This has questions on protection of financial assetsand protection of intellectual property. 63• UNDP’s Human Development Report (HDR) hasbeen in existence since 1990 and now covers177 countries. This has data on patents grantedto residents. 64• The International Property Rights Index (IPRI) isextremely new, 2007 being <strong>the</strong> first year when<strong>the</strong> index was constructed <strong>for</strong> 70 countries.It covers both physical property rights (PPR)and intellectual property rights (IPR) and alsoincludes a third category titled Legal and PoliticalEnvironment (LP), IPRI being obtained byaggregating across all three categories. 65• Centre on Housing Rights and Evictions (COHRE)has been collecting national data regardingevictions <strong>for</strong> several years. 66 As ‘freedom fromevictions’ should be <strong>the</strong> minimum set of ‘protections/security’to which anyone is entitled, thisindicator is vital to assessing <strong>the</strong> state of legalempowerment regarding land and property rights.COHRE has also developed a tool <strong>for</strong> monitoring<strong>the</strong> ‘Right to Adequate Housing’ which includes asub-index on ‘security of tenure’.• International Land Coalition/CAPRi (Collective Actionon Property Rights) are developing an index<strong>for</strong> common property resources, a crucial issue<strong>for</strong> many rural communities, including indigenousgroups. 67• African Union, <strong>the</strong> Economic Commission <strong>for</strong> Africa,Millennium Challenge Corporation, <strong>the</strong> UN-HABITAT, and World Bank map land indicators <strong>for</strong>Africa. A joint initiative to develop a comprehensiveset of land indicators <strong>for</strong> Africa is to be linkedto, inter alia, <strong>the</strong> African Peer Review Mechanismand <strong>the</strong> Expert Group meeting will be held on 3-4May 2007.• UN-HABITAT Global Urban Observatory has beendeveloping a Secure Tenure Index to monitor Target11 of <strong>the</strong> MDGs related to <strong>the</strong> slum challenge.Secure land tenure is <strong>the</strong> proxy <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> achievementof progress in this target. 68• UN-HABITAT Housing Rights Indicators (HRI)is under development, with <strong>the</strong> United NationsHigh Commissioner <strong>for</strong> Human Rightsand includes an indicator related to security oftenure. 69Labour rights• Since 1997, Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU)has a database on <strong>the</strong> economic and businessenvironment in 120 developed and developingcountries. There is a question on freedom of association.70• Freedom House has three separate rankings, buttwo — nations in transit and countries at <strong>the</strong>crossroads — are only used <strong>for</strong> a limited numberof countries. The one most frequently used isFreedom in <strong>the</strong> World, in existence since 1978,and now with a database of 192 countries. Thereis a question on whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re are free tradeunions or peasant organisations or <strong>the</strong>ir equivalentsand whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re is effective collective bargaining.There is yet ano<strong>the</strong>r question on whe<strong>the</strong>r<strong>the</strong>re is equality of opportunity, which includesfreedom from exploitation by, or dependency on,landlords, employers, union leaders, bureaucratsor any o<strong>the</strong>r obstacle that prevents access to legitimateeconomic gains. 71347


• Since 1996, Institute <strong>for</strong> Management Developmentbrings out a World Competitiveness Yearbookthat has data on 49 developed and developingcountries. This has a question on whe<strong>the</strong>rlabour regulations hinder business activities. 72• UNDP’s Human Development Report (HDR) hasbeen in existence since 1990 and now covers177 countries. Data on ratification of some conventions(child labour, elimination of discriminationagainst women, elimination of <strong>for</strong>ced andcompulsory labour, freedom of association andcollective bargaining, elimination of all <strong>for</strong>ms ofracial discrimination can be used). 73• The ILO database can be extensively used. Indicatorsare broadly of two categories: those thatcontain in<strong>for</strong>mation on ratification of selectedinternational labour conventions, and those thatmeasure specific aspects of w<strong>ork</strong>, often linked topoverty/empowerment and <strong>the</strong> lack <strong>the</strong>reof. Internationallabour conventions set minimum standards,and in<strong>for</strong>mation on ratification is available<strong>for</strong> 180 member countries. 74 Ratification doesn’tsolve <strong>the</strong> problem of implementation per se, butratification in itself signifies political will. Theratified convention database can be divided intothree broad segments, beyond which <strong>the</strong>re is arich database on statistics: 751. Eight fundamental conventions that concernfundamental principles and rights atw<strong>ork</strong>, such as Conventions 29 and 105 onelimination of <strong>for</strong>ced labour, Conventions 138and 182 on child labour, Conventions 100and 105 on discrimination in employment andprotection, and Conventions 87 and 98 onfreedom of association and right to engage incollective bargaining.2. Conventions that provide a basic institutionalframew<strong>ork</strong> aimed at protecting againstexploitation, such as Convention 95 on protectionof wages, Convention 155 on occupationalsafety and health, Convention 81 onlabour inspection, Convention 129 on labourinspection <strong>for</strong> agriculture, Convention 144 ontripartite consultation, and Convention 122 onemployment policy.3. Conventions that address situations thatoverlap with poverty, as, <strong>for</strong> example, Convention149 on indigenous and tribal people, 76Conventions 97 and 143 on migration <strong>for</strong>employment and migrant w<strong>ork</strong>ers, Convention183 on maternity protection, and Convention137 on rural w<strong>ork</strong>ers’ organisations.Business• Business Environment Risk Intelligence’s OperationRisk Index (ORI) has data on 50 countriessince 1996 and has a question on bureaucraticdelays. 77• Columbia University’s State Capacity Survey hasdata since 1999, on 108 countries and has aquestion on <strong>the</strong> severity of corruption within <strong>the</strong>state and several separate questions on nepotism,cronyism and patronage. 78• The World Bank’s Country Policy and InstitutionalAssessment (CPIA) database has data on 136 developingcountries; <strong>the</strong> creation of <strong>the</strong> databasegoes back to <strong>the</strong> late 1970s. There is a questionon transparency, accountability and corruption in<strong>the</strong> public sector. 79• Since 1997, Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU)has a database on <strong>the</strong> economic and businessenvironment in 120 developed and developingcountries. There are three separate questions onorderly transfers, vested interests and accountabilityof public officials. There is a separate questionon excessive bureaucracy/red tape. There isa separate question on corruption among publicofficials. 80• Freedom House has three separate rankings, buttwo nations in transit and countries at <strong>the</strong> cross-348


oads — cover only a limited number of countries.The one that can be used freely is Freedom in <strong>the</strong>World, in existence since 1978 and now with adatabase of 192 countries. There are two separatequestions on whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re are free professionaland o<strong>the</strong>r private organisations and whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>reare free businesses or cooperatives. There is alsoa question on whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re is freedom from extremegovernment indifference, and corruption. 81• Since 2004, Transparency International and Galluphave <strong>the</strong> Global Barometer Survey <strong>for</strong> 69 developedand developing countries. There are fiveseparate questions on percentage who believe <strong>the</strong>government is corrupt, frequency of corruption,frequency of household bribery, extent of grandcorruption and extent of petty corruption. 82• Since 1996, Global Insight’s Global Risk Servicecovers 117 developed and developing countriesand has a question on costs of corruption. 83• Since 1996, Global Insight’s Business Conditionsand Risks Indicators, covers 202 developedand developing countries. This has two separatequestions on whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> necessary business lawsare in place and whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re are outstandinggaps and on corruption. 84• Since 1995, Heritage Foundation and <strong>the</strong> WallStreet Journal produce an index of economic freedomthat covers 161 countries. This has a questionon corruption. 85• Since 1996, Institute <strong>for</strong> Management Developmentbrings out a World Competitiveness Yearbookthat has data on 49 developed and developingcountries. This has three separate questionson ease of starting a business, <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> paralleleconomy and bribery and corruption. 86• Since 1982, Merchant International Group Limitedhas data <strong>for</strong> 155 developed and developingcountries. This has a question on corruption. 87• Since 1982, Political Risk Services producesdata on country risks. The financial and economicrisk categories don’t interest <strong>the</strong> Commission. Butwithin <strong>the</strong> political risk category (140 developingand developed countries), <strong>the</strong>re is a question oncorruption. 88• The World Bank’s World Business EnvironmentSurvey has existed since 1998 and covers 80 developedand developing countries. This has questionson regulations on starting new businesses,dishonesty in courts, frequency of additional payments,corruption as obstacle to business andbribery. 89• Since 1996, World Economic Forum has broughtout <strong>the</strong> Global Competitiveness Report and thiscovers 104 developed and developing countries.This has questions on ease of starting a company,burden of administrative regulations, percentageof firms that are unofficial/unregistered, frequencyof bribery, frequency of firms making extra paymentsand <strong>the</strong> extent to which firms’ illegal paymentsor influence impose costs on o<strong>the</strong>r firms. 90349


Chapter 5 Endnotes1 These international agreements include <strong>the</strong> UniversalDeclaration of Human Rights (UDHR), <strong>the</strong> International Covenant onCivil and Political Rights (ICCPR) and <strong>the</strong> International Covenant onEconomic and Social Rights (ICESR), ILO fundamental Conventionson freedom of association/collective bargaining, and elimination of<strong>for</strong>ced labour, child labour and discrimination; and <strong>for</strong> indigenouspeoples, <strong>the</strong> Indigenous and Tribal Peoples Convention, 1989(ILO Convention No. 169). In addition, <strong>the</strong>re is an internationallyrecognised ‘Right to Adequate Housing,’ which includes security oftenure as one of its six components.2 Two useful approaches to analysing stakeholder interestsin development are DFID’s drivers of change (http://www.gsdrc.org/go/topic-guides/drivers-of-change) and SIDA’s power analysis(http://www.sida.se/sida/jsp/sida.jsp?d=118&a=24300&language=en_US).3 Stakeholder analysis is a standard strategic management tool.It is often applied to development programmes and policies. See,<strong>for</strong> example, <strong>the</strong> Overseas Development Institute’s Tools <strong>for</strong> PolicyImpact. Start and Hovland. 2004 and Chapter 5 of <strong>the</strong> InternationalDevelopment Research Centre’s text on Cultivating Peace, by(Ramirez. 1999. Also see Bianchi and Kossoudji, 2001.4 ‘Rent seeking’ refers to ef<strong>for</strong>ts to get government to createeconomic rents, which can <strong>the</strong>n be captured <strong>for</strong> private gain.Economic rent is simply extra income that would not exist in acompetitive marketplace. Rent-seeking behavior benefi ts <strong>the</strong>individual doing it, but is a loss <strong>for</strong> society due to <strong>the</strong> ineffi ciencies itcreates.5 Where a country has ratifi ed <strong>the</strong> United Nations Convention onCorruption (140 have done so to date), <strong>for</strong>mal political commitment(if not true political will) already exists to fi ght corruption.6 There are tools that have been used <strong>for</strong> refugee return andrestitution in <strong>the</strong> Balkans and in Afghanistan that are useful in thisregard (e.g., Aursnes and Foley 2005).7 This typology is based on one that fi rst appeared inWilson.1973., ch. 16. Similar matrixes are widely used in publicadministration and development texts (e.g., Brinkerhoff and Crosby2002).8 A side payment is a term from game <strong>the</strong>ory referring to acompensation paid to <strong>the</strong> game’s loser. Logrolling is <strong>the</strong> exchangingof political favours to support projects that are of interest only to oneside or <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r.9 See <strong>for</strong> example <strong>the</strong> w<strong>ork</strong> of <strong>the</strong> ‘Barefoot College’ (Social W<strong>ork</strong>and Research Centre) in Vilonia, Rajasthan, India.10 Development practitioners wanting to mix and match toolsmay refer to <strong>the</strong> following easily found toolkits and handbooks: TheAccess Initiative Assessment Toolkit (www.accessinitiative.org/how_to_guide.html); <strong>the</strong> World Bank/International Council on Miningand Metals Community Development Toolkit (http://www.icmm.com/library_pub_detail.php?rcd=183); <strong>the</strong> UNDP’s Practitioner’s Guide onAccess to Justice (www.undp.org/governance/guidelines-toolkits.htm);<strong>the</strong> Housing and Land Rights Netw<strong>ork</strong> of <strong>the</strong> Habitat InternationalCoalition toolkit <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> ‘housing rights defender’ (www.toolkit.hlrn.org/English/start.htm); <strong>the</strong> Overseas Development Institute’s Researchand Policy in Development (RAPID) Toolkits (http://www.odi.org.uk/publications/toolkit2.html); USAID’s toolkit <strong>for</strong> situations where <strong>the</strong>reis a link between land rights (or <strong>the</strong>ir lack) and confl ict (www.usaid.gov/our_w<strong>ork</strong>/cross-cutting_programmes/confl ict/publications/docs/CMM_Land_and_Confl ict_Toolkit_April_2005.pdf); <strong>the</strong> Core LabourStandards Handbook, co-published by <strong>the</strong> Asian Development Bankand ILO (www.adb.org/Documents/Handbooks/Core-Labor-Standards/default.asp); <strong>the</strong> ILO’s toolkit <strong>for</strong> mainstreaming employmentand decent w<strong>ork</strong>: http://www.ilo.org/public/english/bureau/dgo/selecdoc/2007/toolkit.pdf; Transparency International’s corruptionfi ghters’ toolkits <strong>for</strong> monitoring public institutions and demandingand promoting accountable and responsive public administration(www.transparency.org/tools/e_toolkit); <strong>the</strong> CIVICUS and Aga KhanFoundation resource mobilisation toolkit (http://www.akdn.org/agency/akf_trainer.html). See Annex 2 <strong>for</strong> a comprehensive inventory oftoolkits.11 Available at http://go.worldbank.org/KUDGZ5E6P0.12 The World Resources Institute is one organisation that hasdeveloped participatory monitoring and evaluation techniques. Thesemay be adapted <strong>for</strong> use in Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor activitiesto help countries track progress (and lost ground), and allow <strong>the</strong>mensure that re<strong>for</strong>ms actually do lead to empowerment of <strong>the</strong> poor. Alsosee <strong>the</strong> Participatory Methods Toolkit prepared by <strong>the</strong> King BaudouinFoundation and <strong>the</strong> Flemish Institute <strong>for</strong> Science and TechnologyAssessment: http://www.viwta.be/fi les/ToolkitPartAssessment.pdf.13 www.accessinitiative.org/how_to_guide.html .14 www.unodc.org/unodc/criminal_justice_assessment_toolkit.html15 Programmeming <strong>for</strong> Justice: Access <strong>for</strong> All, UNDP, 2005, www.undp.org/governance/guidelines-toolkits.htm, especially Chapter 2.16 Gender, <strong>Law</strong>, and Policy in ADB Operations: A Tool Kit, 2006,www.adb.org/Documents/Manuals/Gender-Toolkit/Gender-<strong>Law</strong>-Policy-Toolkit.asp17 The Housing and Land Rights monitoring ‘Toolkit’, 2005, www.toolkit.hlrn.org/English/start.htm18 Land & Confl ict, A Toolkit <strong>for</strong> Intervention, USAID, 2005, www.usaid.gov/our_w<strong>ork</strong>/cross-cutting_programmes/confl ict/publications/docs/CMM_Land_and_Confl ict_Toolkit_April_2005.pdf19 Minerals & Confl ict, A Toolkit <strong>for</strong> Intervention, USAID, 2004,www.iisd.org/pdf/2004/envsec_minerals_confl ict.pdf20 Forests & Confl ict, A Toolkit <strong>for</strong> Intervention, USAID, 2005, www.usaid.gov/our_w<strong>ork</strong>/cross-cutting_programmes/confl ict/publications/docs/CMM_Forests_and_Confl ict_2005.pdf21 Core Labour Standards Handbook, ADB and ILO, 2006, www.adb.org/Documents/Handbooks/Core-Labour-Standards/default.asp.22 Labour Issues in Infrastructure Re<strong>for</strong>m: A Toolkit, PPIAF, 2004,www.ebookmall.com/ebook/168641-ebook.htm23 Labour Issues in Public Enterprise Restructuring, TechnicalNote, Asian Development Bank, 2006, available at www.adb.org/Documents/Reports/Labor-Issues-PublicEnterpriseRestructuring/Labor-Issues-PER.pdf24 Geneva 2005.25 http://www.ilo.org/dyn/infoecon/iebrowse.search?p_lang=en26 http://www.ilo.org/public/english/dialogue/ifpdial/llg/index.htm27 http://www.ilo.org/ipecinfo/product/viewProduct.do;jsessionid=0a038009ce90d3a489e22af427195a29dfeb2dc51ec?productId=3060350


28 http://www.ilo.org/dyn/gender/genderresources.details?p_lang=en&p_category=NEW&p_resource_id=31329 http://www.ilo.org/dyn/gender/genderresources.details?p_lang=en&p_category=NEW&p_resource_id=30930 http://www.ilo.org/dyn/gender/genderresources.details?p_lang=en&p_category=NEW&p_resource_id=13831 Business Licensing Re<strong>for</strong>m: A Toolkit <strong>for</strong> DevelopmentPractitioners, The World Bank Group, 2006, available at www.businessenvironment.org/dyn/be/docs/137/LicensingRe<strong>for</strong>m32 Good Practices <strong>for</strong> Business Inspections, Guidelines <strong>for</strong>Re<strong>for</strong>mers, Small and Medium Enterprises Department, TheWorld Bank Group, 2006, available at www.ifc.org/ifcext/sme.nsf/AttachmentsByTitle/BEEGood+Practices+<strong>for</strong>+Business+Inspection/$FILE/Bus+Inspect+Book.pdf33 Re<strong>for</strong>ming Business Registration Regulatory Procedures at<strong>the</strong> National Level, A Re<strong>for</strong>m Toolkit <strong>for</strong> Project Teams, Small andMedium Enterprises Department, The World Bank Group, 2006,available at www.ifc.org/ifcext/sme.nsf/AttachmentsByTitle/BEERe<strong>for</strong>mBusRegNational/$File/Bus+Reg+book.pdf34 Simplifi cation of Business Regulations at <strong>the</strong> Sub-NationalLevel, A Re<strong>for</strong>m Implementation Toolkit <strong>for</strong> Project Teams, InternationalFinance Corporation, The World Bank Group, 2006, available at www.ifc.org/ifcext/sme.nsf/AttachmentsByTitle/BEESubnational/$File/BeeToolkit05_full.pdf35 The Commonwealth Youth Credit Initiative Toolkit,Commonwealth Secretariat, 2002.36 http://topics.developmentgateway.org/microfi nance/rc/ItemDetail.do~1053.37 Anti-Corruption Toolkit, United Nations Offi ce on Drugs andCrime, 2004, available at www.unodc.org/unodc/corruption_toolkit.html38 www.transparency.org/tools/e_toolkit39 http://www.bertelsmann-trans<strong>for</strong>mation-index.de/atlas.0.html?&L=140 http://www.beri.com41 http://www.columbia.edu42 http://www.columbia.edu43 http://www.eiu.com44 http://www.freedomhouse.org45 http://www.gallup-international.com46 http://www.globalinsight.com47 http://www.globalinsight.com48 http://www.heritage.org49 http://www.imd.ch50 http://www.merchantinternational.com51 http://www.prsgroup.com52 http://www.state.gov/g/tip/rls/tiprpt/53 http://www.humanrightsdata.com54 http://www.ifc.org/ifcext/economics.nsf/Content/IC-WBESConditions55 http://www.we<strong>for</strong>um.org56 http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERN<strong>AL</strong>/DATASTATISTICS57 http://research.accessinitiative.org/?module=research.methodology58 http://www.bertelsmann-trans<strong>for</strong>mation-index.de/atlas.0.html?&L=159 http://www.worldbank.org60 http://www.eiu.com61 http://www.imd.ch62 http://www.ifc.org/ifcext/economics.nsf/Content/IC-WBESConditions63 http://www.we<strong>for</strong>um.org64 http://www.undp.org65 http://internationalpropertyrightsindex.org/index.php?content=home66 http://www.cohre.org67 http://www.landcoalition.org/programme/polcompropstudy.htm68 http://millenniumindicators.un.org/unsd/mdg/Metadata.aspx?IndicatorId=3269 http://www.unhabitat.org70 http://www.eiu.com71 http://www.freedomhouse.org72 http://www.imd.ch73 http://www.undp.org74 http://.www.ilo.org/ilolex75 Obviously relevant only if such people exist in <strong>the</strong> countryconcerned.76 http://laborsta.ilo.org. Employment in <strong>the</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mal economy,child labour statistics, decent w<strong>ork</strong> indicators, <strong>for</strong>ced labour andgender discrimination are instances of areas where this databasecan be mined.77 http://www.beri.com78 http://www.columbia.edu79 http://www.worldbank.org80 http://www.eiu.com81 http://www.freedomhouse.org82 http://www.gallup-international.com83 http://www.globalinsight.com84 http://www.globalinsight.com85 http://www.heritage.org86 http://www.imd.ch87 http://www.merchantinternational.com88 http://www.prsgroup.com89 http://www.ifc.org/ifcext/economics.nsf/Content/IC-WBESConditions90 http://www.we<strong>for</strong>um.org351


Chapter 5 BibliographyAbdul-Jalil, Musa Adam. 2005. ‘Land Tenure and Inter-EthnicConfl ict in Darfur,’ in Report of <strong>the</strong> Conference on LandTenure and Confl ict in Africa: Prevention, Mitigation andReconstruction. Nairobi: ACTS Press.Alsop, Ruth, and Nina Heinsohn. 2005. Measuring Empowerment inPractice: Structuring Analysis and Framew<strong>ork</strong> Indicators,World Bank Policy Research W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper No. 3510.Arndt, Christiane, and Charles Oman. 2006. Uses and Abuses ofGovernance Indicators, OECD Development Centre Study.Assaad, Ragui. 1996. Formalizing <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal? The Trans<strong>for</strong>mationof Cairo’s Refuse Collection System, Journal of PlanningEducation and Research 16 (2), 115-126.Aursnes, Ingunn Sofi e, and Conor Foley. 2005. (April) PropertyRestitution in Practice: The Norwegian Refugee Councils’Experience, Norwegian Refugee Council.Barrett, Jane. 2003. Organising in <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Economy: A Case Studyof <strong>the</strong> Minibus Taxi Industry in South Africa, SEED W<strong>ork</strong>ingPaper No.39, ILO.Berg, Janine, and Sandrine Cazes. 2007. The Doing BusinessIndicators: Measurement Issues and Political Implications,ILO Economic and Labour Market Papers 2007/6, Geneva.Bianchi, Robert R. and Sherrie A. Kossoudji. 2001. Interest Groupsand Organisations as Stakeholders, World Bank, SocialDevelopment Papers No. 35.Brinkerhoff, Derick W. 2000. ‘Assessing Political Will <strong>for</strong> Anti-Corruption Ef<strong>for</strong>ts: An Analytic Framew<strong>ork</strong>.’ PublicAdministration and Development 20 (3), 239-252.Brinkerhoff, Derick W., and Benjamin L. Crosby. 2002. ManagingPolicy Re<strong>for</strong>m, Concepts and Tools <strong>for</strong> Decision-Makersin Developing and Transition Countries, Bloomfi eld, CT,Kumarian Press.Brinkerhoff, Derick W., and Arthur A. Goldsmith. 2004. ‘GoodGovernance, Clientelism and Patrimonialism: NewPerspectives on Old Problems.’International PublicManagement Journal 7 (2), 163-185._______. 2005. ‘Institutional Dualism and InternationalDevelopment: A Revisionist Interpretation of GoodGovernance.’ Administration and Society 37 (2), 199-224.Bruce, John W. et al. 1996. Country Profi les of Land Tenure: Africa,University of Wisconsin, Land Tenure Center.Cook, Maria L. 2005. ‘International Labor Standards and DomesticLabor Advocates: The Politics of Labor Rights in LatinAmerica.’ Paper presented at <strong>the</strong> annual meeting of <strong>the</strong>American Political Science Association .Washington, DC.Cotula, Lorenzo. 2007. Legal Empowerment <strong>for</strong> Local Resource Control.International Institute <strong>for</strong> Environment and Development.Cousins, Ben et al. 2005. ‘Will Formalizing Property Rights ReducePoverty in South Africa’s ‘Second Economy’? ‘ <strong>for</strong> Land andAgrarian Studies. School of Government. University of <strong>the</strong>Western Cape, South Africa.Decker, Klaus, Caroline Sage, and Milena Stefanova. 2005. <strong>Law</strong> orJustice: Building Equitable Legal Institutions. World Bank,WDR 2006 Background Paper.Eurostat/UNDP. 2004. Governance Indicators: A Users’ Guide.Luxembourg and New Y<strong>ork</strong>.Fung, Archon, and Erik O. Wright 2003. ‘Countervailing Power inEmpowered Participatory Governance.’ In Fung and Wright,eds. Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations inEmpowered Participatory Governance. Fung and Wright,eds., London: Verso.Golub, Stephen. 2003. Beyond Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Orthodoxy: The LegalEmpowerment Alternative, Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Series No. 41,Carnegie Endowment <strong>for</strong> International Peace.Grindle, Merilee. 2007. Good Enough Governance Revisited,Development Policy Review 25 (5), 533-574.Hart, Stuart L. 2005. Capitalism at <strong>the</strong> Crossroads: The UnlimitedBusiness Opportunities in Solving <strong>the</strong> World’s Most Diffi cultProblems, Upper Saddle River, NJ, Wharton School.He, Xin. 2005. ‘Why Do They Not Comply with <strong>the</strong> <strong>Law</strong>? Illegality andSemi-Legality among Rural-Urban Migrant Entrepreneursin Beijing.’ <strong>Law</strong> and Society Review 39 (3), 527-562.ILO. 2001. Stopping Forced Labour, Geneva, available at http://www.ilo.org/dyn/declaris/DECLARATIONWEB.DOWNLOAD_BLOB?Var_DocumentID=1578._______. 2003. W<strong>ork</strong>ing out of Poverty, Geneva, available athttp://www.ilo.org/global/About_<strong>the</strong>_ILO/Mainpillars/W<strong>ork</strong>ingoutofpoverty/lang--en/docName--KD00116/index.htm._______. 2004. Organising <strong>for</strong> Social Justice, Geneva, availableat http://www.ilo.org/public/english/employment/strat/analysis/poverty.htm._______. 2007. Equality at W<strong>ork</strong>: Tackling <strong>the</strong> Challenges. Geneva.Available at http://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---dgreports/---dcomm/---webdev/documents/publication/wcms_082607.pdfICMM, <strong>the</strong> World Bank and ESMAP. 2005. Community DevelopmentToolkit. Available at http://www.icmm.com/publications/1342CDT.pdf.Kamunyori, Sheila Wanjiru. 2007. ‘A Growing Space <strong>for</strong> Dialogue:The Case of Street Vending in Nairobi’s Central BusinessDistrict,’ unpublished Masters Thesis. MassachusettsInstitute of Technology.Kucera, David, ed. 2007. Qualitative Indicators of Labour Standards:Comparative Methods and Applications. Dordrecht:Springer.Le Sage, Andre. 2005. Stateless Justice in Somalia: Formal andIn<strong>for</strong>mal Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Initiatives. Geneva, Centre <strong>for</strong>Humanitarian Dialogue.Lindenberg, Marc, and Shantayanan Devarajan. 1993. ‘PrescribingStrong Economic Medicine: Revisiting <strong>the</strong> Myths aboutStructural Adjustment, Democracy, and EconomicPer<strong>for</strong>mance in Developing Countries.’ Comparative Politics25 (2), 169-182.Moser, Caroline. 2005. An Introduction to Gender Audit Methodology.London: Overseas Development Institute.Örtengren, Kari. 2004. The Logical Framew<strong>ork</strong> Approach: A Summary of<strong>the</strong> Theory behind <strong>the</strong> LFA Method, SIDA, available at www.sida.se/publications.352


Ouchi, Fumika. 2004. Twinning as a Method <strong>for</strong> InstitutionalDevelopment: A Desk Review, WBI Evaluation Studies EG04-85. Available at http://info.worldbank.org/etools/docs/library/80333/EG04-85.pdfPalacio, Ana. 2006. Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor: An Action Agenda<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> World Bank. Available at http://rru.worldbank.org/Documents/PSDForum/2006/background/legal_empowerment_of_poor.pdf.Patel, Sheela. 2007. Towards <strong>the</strong> Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor.Available at http://www.undp.org/LegalEmpowerment/docs/SheelaPatel_towards_Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor.doc.Perry, Guillermo E. 2007. In<strong>for</strong>mality: Exit and Exclusion. Washington,DC: World Bank.Platteau, Jean-Philippe. 2004. ‘Monitoring Elite Capture in Community-Driven Development.’ Development and Change. 35 (2),223—246.Pozzoni, Barbara, and Nalini Kumar. 2005. A Review of <strong>the</strong> Literatureon Participatory Approaches to Local Development <strong>for</strong> anEvaluation of <strong>the</strong> Effectiveness of World Bank Support <strong>for</strong>Community-Based and Driven Development Approaches.Washington, DC: World Bank. Operations EvaluationDepartment W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper.Pur, Kripa Ananth, and Mick Moore. 2007. Ambiguous Institutions:Traditional Governance and Local Democracy in Rural India.IDS W<strong>ork</strong>ing Paper 282.Radel, Claudia. 2005. ‘Women’s Community-Based Organisations,Conservation Projects, and Effective Land Control inSou<strong>the</strong>rn Mexico.’ Journal of Latin American Geography 4,(2), 7-34.Ramirez, Ricardo. 1999. ‘Stakeholder Analysis and Confl ictManagement.’ In: Cultivating Peace: Confl ict andCollaboration in Natural Resource Management. ed. DanielBuckles. Ottawa: International Development ResearchCentre.Ribot, Jesse C. 1999. Decentralisation, Participation and Accountabilityin Sahelian Forestry: Legal Instruments of Political-Administrative Control, Africa: Journal of <strong>the</strong> InternationalAfrican Institute, 69 (1), 23-65.Robb, C. M. 2000. How <strong>the</strong> Poor Can Have a Voice in Government Policy,Finance & Development 37 (4). Available at http://www.fao.org/Participation/ft_more.jsp?ID=2163.Ross, Michael. 2006. ‘Is Democracy Good <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor?’ AmericanJournal of Political Science. 50 (4), 860-874.Samuels, Kirsti. 2006. Rule of <strong>Law</strong> Re<strong>for</strong>m in Post-Confl ict Countries:Operational Initiatives and Lessons Learnt. World Bank.Confl ict Prevention and Reconstruction Paper No. 37.Schneider, Friedrich. 2002. Size and Measurement of <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>malEconomy in 110 Countries around <strong>the</strong> World. DoingBusiness project. World Bank w<strong>ork</strong>ing paper. July.Shatkin, Gavin. 2000. Obstacles to Empowerment: Local Politics andCivil Society in Metropolitan Manila, The Philippines, UrbanStudies. 37 (12), 2357-2375.Start, Daniel, and Ingie Hovland. 2004. Tools <strong>for</strong> Policy Impact: AHandbook <strong>for</strong> Researchers, London, Overseas DevelopmentInstitute.Stern, Nicholas, Jean-Jacques Dethier, and F. Halsey Rogers. 2005.Growth and Empowerment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Tendler, Judith. 2002. ‘Small Firms, <strong>the</strong> In<strong>for</strong>mal Sector, and <strong>the</strong> Devil’sDeal.’ IDS Bulletin 33 (3), 98-104.UN Global Compact Offi ce. 2007. UN Global Compact Annual Review.New Y<strong>ork</strong>.UNEP. 2004. Women and <strong>the</strong> Environment. Nairobi.USAID. 1998. Handbook of Democracy and Governance ProgrammeIndicators, Center <strong>for</strong> Democracy and Governance,Washington.van der Merwe, Susan. 2007. ‘A Policy Perspective from South Africa.’In In<strong>for</strong>mal Institutions: How Social Norms Help or HinderDevelopment. Paris: OECD Development Centre.Varshney, Ashutosh. 2005. ‘Democracy and Poverty.’ In MeasuringEmpowerment. ed., Deepa Narayan-Parker. New Y<strong>ork</strong>:Ox<strong>for</strong>d University Press.Viswanathan, Sujatha, and Ravi Srivastava 2007. Learning from <strong>the</strong>Poor, Manila, Asian Development Bank.Wampler, Brian. 2007. Participatory Budgeting in Brazil: Contestation,Cooperation, and Accountability. University Park:Pennsylvania State University Press.Wells, A., et al. 2004. Rural Livelihoods, Forest <strong>Law</strong> and <strong>the</strong> IllegalTimber Trade in Honduras and Nicaragua, Research paper<strong>for</strong> CIFOR, Bogor Barat.Wilson, James Q.1973. Political Organisations, New Y<strong>ork</strong>: Basic Books.World Bank. 1996. Participation Sourcebook, Appendix 1: Methods andTools <strong>for</strong> Social Analysis. Available at www.worldbank.org/wbi/sourcebook/sbpdf.htm353


The Commission on Legal Empowerment of <strong>the</strong> Poor aims to make legal protection andeconomic opportunity not <strong>the</strong> privilege of <strong>the</strong> few but <strong>the</strong> right of all.This is a wholly different approach to <strong>the</strong>poverty debate …our Commission will focus ona unique and overlooked aspect of <strong>the</strong> problem:<strong>the</strong> inextricable link between pervasive povertyand <strong>the</strong> absence of legal protections <strong>for</strong><strong>the</strong> poor.– Madeleine K. AlbrightThe law is not something that you invent in auniversity – <strong>the</strong> law is something that youdiscover. Poor people already have agreementsamong <strong>the</strong>mselves, social contracts, and what youhave to do is professionally standardize <strong>the</strong>secontracts to create one legal system that everybodyrecognizes and obeys.– Hernando de Sotowww.undp.org/legalempowermentdesign: cynthiaspence.com

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!