12.07.2015 Views

Migration Magnet: The role of work experience in rural-urban wage ...

Migration Magnet: The role of work experience in rural-urban wage ...

Migration Magnet: The role of work experience in rural-urban wage ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Migration</strong> <strong>Magnet</strong>: <strong>The</strong> <strong>role</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> <strong>in</strong><strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> dierentials <strong>in</strong> MexicoMaren M. Michaelsen ∗a and John P. Haisken-DeNew ba Ruhr University <strong>of</strong> Bochum, RUB Research Schoolb Ruhr University <strong>of</strong> Bochum, McMaster University, RWI, IZANovember 2010Prelim<strong>in</strong>ary Version. Please do not citeAbstractThis study estimates separate selectivity bias corrected <strong>wage</strong> equations for formaland <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> Mexico us<strong>in</strong>g data from the MexicanFamily Life Survey (MxFLS). Oaxaca-Bl<strong>in</strong>der Decompositions show that<strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector is ma<strong>in</strong>ly expla<strong>in</strong>ed by differences<strong>in</strong> returns to <strong>experience</strong>. In the formal sector, dierences <strong>in</strong> averageeducation expla<strong>in</strong> the <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> gap. <strong>The</strong> nd<strong>in</strong>gs suggest that <strong>rural</strong>to-<strong>urban</strong>migration will cont<strong>in</strong>ue and the <strong>in</strong>formal sector will further <strong>in</strong>crease.Keywords: Returns to <strong>experience</strong>, <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> dierentials, <strong>in</strong>formality,<strong>in</strong>ternal migration, MexicoJEL classications: J24, J31, R23, Q15∗ Submitt<strong>in</strong>g and correspond<strong>in</strong>g author. Email: maren.michaelsen@rub.de; Phone: +49-234-32-23938; Fax: +49-234-32-143111


1 Introduction<strong>The</strong>ories <strong>of</strong> economic development postulate that <strong>rural</strong>-to-<strong>urban</strong> migration is thedriv<strong>in</strong>g force <strong>of</strong> a country's development. Follow<strong>in</strong>g Todaro (1969) and Harris andTodaro (1970) people migrate from <strong>rural</strong> to <strong>urban</strong> areas to nd well paid employmentwhich is not available <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas. If migrants do not nd a job with higher rewardsthan their reservation <strong>wage</strong> they will stay unemployed or return. In this model theunemployment rate acts as the driv<strong>in</strong>g force on a migration equilibrium. <strong>The</strong> theoryis extended by Lucas (2004) who argues that high <strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong>s are attributed to highskills and not accessible for low skilled immigrants. In his model, <strong>in</strong>dividuals migrateto the cities to accumulate <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> as a form <strong>of</strong> human capital formation.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to human capital theory (Becker 1964), the accumulation <strong>of</strong> <strong>experience</strong>will raise future earn<strong>in</strong>gs prospective. This will <strong>in</strong> turn reduce poverty and welfaredependency. Follow<strong>in</strong>g this augmentation, the two ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives to migrate are(1) earn<strong>in</strong>g high <strong>wage</strong>s and (2) the accumulation <strong>of</strong> human capital.This implies that <strong>wage</strong>s are higher <strong>in</strong> the cities than <strong>in</strong> the countryside, whichhas been demonstrated by economists for decades. Besides the <strong>wage</strong> dierencesbetween <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> areas, there are also <strong>wage</strong> dierences between the types<strong>of</strong> job a <strong>work</strong>er can get, i.e. a formal job or an <strong>in</strong>formal job. Early theories byLewis (1954) and Fields (1975) suggest that the <strong>in</strong>formal sector is the disadvantagedsegment <strong>of</strong> a dualistic labour market <strong>in</strong> which <strong>work</strong>ers are not protected by socialsecurity regulations and are <strong>in</strong> vulnerable barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g positions with their employers.However, <strong>in</strong> the last decades, some develop<strong>in</strong>g countries show a reversed development:the <strong>in</strong>formal sector has been <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g. This has aroused the <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>of</strong> economiststo test the segmented market hypothesis empirically. For Mexico, e.g. Maloney(1999), Maloney (2004), Marcouiller, de Castilla and Woodru (1997) and Barga<strong>in</strong>and Kwenda (2009) show that <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong> is <strong>in</strong>deed voluntary for reasons such asopportunity costs and exibility. Hence, <strong>in</strong>stead <strong>of</strong> queu<strong>in</strong>g for a formal job, peopleearn <strong>wage</strong>s and accumulate human capital <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector.In Mexico, as <strong>in</strong> many other countries, <strong>wage</strong> dierentials have many dimensions,e.g. between <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> employment and between formal and <strong>in</strong>formal sectors.An <strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> premium is enhanc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rural</strong>-to-<strong>urban</strong> migration which <strong>in</strong> turn leads tosocial and economic problems, such as un- and underemployment, poverty, crime andan <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formal sector rather than to economic development. Figure 1 showsthe decrease <strong>of</strong> the <strong>rural</strong> population and the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>of</strong> population density <strong>in</strong> four<strong>of</strong> Mexico's largest cities, namely Mexico City, Guadalajara, Puebla and Monterrey.It shows that between 1995 and 2008 the <strong>rural</strong> population decreased from 27 to23% while population density <strong>in</strong> the cities rised. All four example cities show a1


Figure 1: Population <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>urban</strong> areasa Source: <strong>The</strong> World Bank (http://data.worldbank.org/country/mexico) and OECD Metropolitan database(http://stats.oecd.org/<strong>in</strong>dex.aspx)similar development, i.e. an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> population density <strong>of</strong> about 23% with<strong>in</strong> 14years, which is approximately 1.5% per year. Furthermore, Figure 2 displays thedevelopment <strong>of</strong> the <strong>urban</strong> and total open unemployment rate <strong>in</strong> Mexico over theperiod mid-2000 to mid-2006 and the rise <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal employment over the sameperiod. It can be seen that the <strong>urban</strong> unemployment rate is much larger than totalopen unemployment rate, but but exhibits the same pattern. Moreover, the higherthe unemployment rate is, the larger is the <strong>in</strong>formal sector share. Comb<strong>in</strong>ed withFigure 1, these macroeconomic <strong>in</strong>dicators suggest that the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong>-to-<strong>urban</strong>migration, ris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>urban</strong> population density, more unemployment and larger <strong>in</strong>formalsector shares go hand <strong>in</strong> hand.Figure 2: Unemployment rates and <strong>in</strong>formal sector sharea Source: INEGI (http://www.<strong>in</strong>egi.org.mx/)Still, <strong>in</strong>dividuals migrate to the cities. Mexico's <strong>urban</strong> population grew from 66%to 76% between 1980 and 2005, with Mexico City compris<strong>in</strong>g 29% <strong>of</strong> the <strong>urban</strong> pop-2


ulation <strong>in</strong> 1980 but only 23% <strong>in</strong> 2005 (World Bank 2010).We contribute to theexplanations <strong>of</strong> the driv<strong>in</strong>g forces <strong>of</strong> <strong>rural</strong>-to-<strong>urban</strong> migration <strong>in</strong> Mexico by <strong>in</strong>vestigat<strong>in</strong>gthe dierences <strong>in</strong> <strong>wage</strong>s between <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> areas. Focus<strong>in</strong>g on theargument that <strong>rural</strong>-to-<strong>urban</strong> migration is <strong>in</strong>duced by the <strong>in</strong>centive to accumulatehuman capital <strong>in</strong> form <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong>, this paper analyses the returns to <strong>work</strong><strong>experience</strong> and other human capital related factors for <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> salaried <strong>work</strong>ers.It is further analysed to what extent these personal endowments can expla<strong>in</strong> the<strong>wage</strong> gap and which <strong>role</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector plays. Mexico's Federal Labour Lawdist<strong>in</strong>guishes between salaried and non-salaried <strong>work</strong>ers by employer or rm dependency.Non-salaried <strong>work</strong>ers, i.e. the self-employed, are excluded from this analysisas their <strong>in</strong>comes need special attention and cannot easily be compared to <strong>wage</strong>s <strong>of</strong>salaried <strong>work</strong>ers. This topic needs to be covered <strong>in</strong> a separate study.<strong>The</strong> Mexican Social Security Law prescribes that salaried <strong>work</strong>ers have to be registeredby their employers with the IMSS (Insitituto Mexicano del Seguro Social).However, there are several <strong>in</strong>centives not to register and simply <strong>work</strong> <strong>in</strong>formallywhich are not mutually exclusive. One is the high price for social security coveragewhich amounts to about 30% <strong>of</strong> a <strong>work</strong>er's <strong>wage</strong> <strong>in</strong> one <strong>of</strong> the lowest three deciles <strong>of</strong>the <strong>wage</strong> distribution (Levy 2008). Furthermore, social security benets have to bebought as a bundle even if the <strong>work</strong>er does not want or need all. Other <strong>in</strong>centives arethe various social protection benets (health <strong>in</strong>surance, hous<strong>in</strong>g subsidies, pensionschemes, access to day care centres and life <strong>in</strong>surance) which can be bought <strong>in</strong>dependentlyand are almost free for poor <strong>work</strong>ers when they are not ocially <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g foran employer. Importantly, non-registration goes hand <strong>in</strong> hand with the avoidance <strong>of</strong>payroll taxes. <strong>The</strong>se are reasons why the Social Security Law is violated massively,lead<strong>in</strong>g to a persist<strong>in</strong>g large share <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal employment. 1Us<strong>in</strong>g the novel and representative Mexican Family Life Survey (MxFLS), this isthe rst study which <strong>in</strong>vestigates <strong>wage</strong> dierentials between <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> areas <strong>in</strong>Mexico. Former studies on <strong>wage</strong> gaps between groups <strong>in</strong> Mexico were restricted to<strong>urban</strong> areas as representative data on the whole population was not available beforethe publication <strong>of</strong> the MxFLS. 2 This study uses the second wave (MxFLS-2) whichconsists <strong>of</strong> data that was collected <strong>in</strong> the second half <strong>of</strong> 2005 and early 2006.To overcome the econometric problem <strong>of</strong> self-selection <strong>in</strong>to <strong>work</strong> as opposed tonot <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g and selection <strong>in</strong>to dierent sectors <strong>of</strong> the labour market, the Heckman(1979) selection-bias correction model is applied. Separate <strong>wage</strong> equations for formaland <strong>in</strong>formal salaried <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> areas are estimated, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g1 See Levy (2008) for a detailed description <strong>of</strong> Social Programs <strong>in</strong> Mexico and their outcomes.2 <strong>The</strong> commonly used Mexican data is the National Urban Employment Survey (ENEU), whichhas only recently been expanded to <strong>rural</strong> areas.3


the generated nonselection hazard from a probit model. We nd the expected largeand signicant <strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> premium <strong>in</strong> both the formal and <strong>in</strong>formal sector. Subsequently,Oaxaca-Bl<strong>in</strong>der decomposition techniques are used to show to which extentthe <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> dierential can be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by <strong>in</strong>dividuals' personal endowmentsdierences and to which extent by dierences <strong>in</strong> unobservable characteristics.<strong>The</strong> results suggest structural dierences between the formal and <strong>in</strong>formal sector. Inthe <strong>in</strong>formal sector, the <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> dierential is expla<strong>in</strong>ed by dierences <strong>in</strong>levels <strong>of</strong> human capital endowments. <strong>The</strong> unexpla<strong>in</strong>ed part however is solely drivenby dierences <strong>in</strong> returns to <strong>experience</strong>. In the formal sector, only dierences <strong>in</strong> observableeducation levels can expla<strong>in</strong> the <strong>wage</strong> dierential. <strong>The</strong> results suggest that<strong>rural</strong>-to-<strong>urban</strong> migration cont<strong>in</strong>ues and the <strong>in</strong>formal sector will further <strong>in</strong>crease.<strong>The</strong> paper is organised as follows. <strong>The</strong> next section reviews the exist<strong>in</strong>g literatureon <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> dierentials and migration <strong>in</strong>centives. Section 3 describesthe empirical strategy to identify <strong>wage</strong> dierentials and account for selectivity bias.Section 4 expla<strong>in</strong>s the data and provides descriptive statistics. Section 5 discussesthe ma<strong>in</strong> nd<strong>in</strong>gs and the last section concludes.2 Literature review<strong>The</strong> literature on <strong>rural</strong>-to-<strong>urban</strong> migration is based on the theoretical models byTodaro (1969) and Harris and Todaro (1970). Accord<strong>in</strong>g to their models, peoplemigrate from <strong>rural</strong> to <strong>urban</strong> areas to nd high <strong>wage</strong> jobs which are not available <strong>in</strong><strong>rural</strong> areas. If people do not nd a job with higher rewards than their reservation <strong>wage</strong>they will stay unemployed or return and the unemployment rate acts as a the driv<strong>in</strong>gforce on a migration equilibrium. This theory is extended by e.g. Lucas (2004) whoargues that <strong>urban</strong> high <strong>wage</strong>s are attributed to high skills and not accessible by lowskilled immigrants. In his model, people migrate to the cities to accumulate <strong>work</strong><strong>experience</strong> as a form <strong>of</strong> human capital.Newer models <strong>of</strong> migration also <strong>in</strong>clude social factors such as previous migration<strong>experience</strong>, net<strong>work</strong>s and <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> the migration decision. One factor that hasreceived much attention <strong>in</strong> recent years and refers to <strong>in</strong>equality is relative deprivation,i.e. the perception <strong>of</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dividual or household to be worse o or disadvantagedcompared to a particular reference group, for example, other people <strong>in</strong> the samevillage (Qu<strong>in</strong>n 2006, Stark and Taylor 1989, Stark and Taylor 1991). Qu<strong>in</strong>n (2006)uses the data from the Mexican <strong>Migration</strong> Project for the year 2004 and nds thatrelative deprivation expla<strong>in</strong>s part <strong>of</strong> the migration decision for <strong>in</strong>ternal migrantsbut not for those who migrate to the United States. Gould (2007) argues that<strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a city <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>work</strong>ers' productivity (see also Glaeser and Maré (2001)).4


Us<strong>in</strong>g the U.S. National Longitud<strong>in</strong>al Survey <strong>of</strong> the Market Experience, he nds thatwhite-collar <strong>work</strong>ers receive a <strong>wage</strong> premium <strong>in</strong> the <strong>rural</strong> areas if they gathered <strong>work</strong><strong>experience</strong> <strong>in</strong> a city, whereas blue collar <strong>work</strong>ers' <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> does notget rewarded more than <strong>rural</strong> <strong>experience</strong>. Hence the <strong>in</strong>centive to accumulate humancapital <strong>in</strong> the city is part <strong>of</strong> the migration decision and return migration is dependenton the occupation.In Mexico, <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>urban</strong>isation has led to economic and social problems suchas <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g under-employment and high crime rates. Also, it has <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>wage</strong><strong>in</strong>equality as more productive and human capital <strong>in</strong>tensive rms settled <strong>in</strong> the citiesand they pay higher <strong>wage</strong>s than <strong>rural</strong> less productive rms. That these higher <strong>wage</strong>sexist for certa<strong>in</strong> groups <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers even after controll<strong>in</strong>g for human capital and otherendowments is shown by e.g. Glaeser and Maré (2001) for the U.S.When <strong>in</strong>vestigat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> dierentials <strong>in</strong> Mexico it has to be taken<strong>in</strong>to account that the labour market is further divided <strong>in</strong>to formal and <strong>in</strong>formalemployment. In fact, many authors do not focus on <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> dierentialsbut on dierences between formal and <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>wage</strong>s. Exemplary studies that nd<strong>wage</strong> penalties for <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector are provided by Barga<strong>in</strong> and Kwenda(2009) and Barga<strong>in</strong> and Kwenda (2010) who compare <strong>in</strong>formal sector <strong>wage</strong> gaps <strong>in</strong>Brazil, South Africa and Mexico. For Mexico, they use the ENEU and restricttheir survey to male dependent <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> <strong>urban</strong> areas. Us<strong>in</strong>g xed eects quantileestimation, they are not able to control for self-selection <strong>in</strong>to sectors but for otherunobserved time-<strong>in</strong>variant characteristics. <strong>The</strong> median penalty for <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formallyis stable dur<strong>in</strong>g 2004-2007 at about 9%. Hanson (2010) and Arias, Azuara, Bernal,Heckman and Villarreal (2010) state that the <strong>in</strong>formal sector <strong>in</strong> Mexico¡s cities has<strong>in</strong>creased which is partly due to perverse registration <strong>in</strong>centives <strong>in</strong>duced by social<strong>in</strong>surance regulations. Furthermore, <strong>in</strong>formality h<strong>in</strong>ders economic development asproductivity is low <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal rms (Hsieh and Klenow 2009).Another study on <strong>wage</strong> dierentials between <strong>in</strong>formal and formal sectors <strong>in</strong> Mexicowas conducted by Gong and van Soest (2002) us<strong>in</strong>g the 1992/1993 waves <strong>of</strong> theENEU, restrict<strong>in</strong>g their sample to <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> Mexico's ve major cities. <strong>The</strong>y applya mult<strong>in</strong>om<strong>in</strong>al logit model with random eects for the sector choice and dynamicrandom eects <strong>wage</strong> regressions. <strong>The</strong>y nd that lagged sector variables are notsignicant and have no eect on current <strong>wage</strong>s. In l<strong>in</strong>e with e.g. Maloney (1999) theynd <strong>wage</strong> dierentials for high educated <strong>work</strong>ers but not for low educated <strong>work</strong>ers.This implies that formal sector jobs are <strong>in</strong>accessible for low educated <strong>work</strong>ers and aneed for labour protection for the poorest <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> Mexico's <strong>urban</strong> areas.For Mexico, many articles have been published <strong>in</strong>vestigat<strong>in</strong>g not only <strong>wage</strong> dier-5


entials but also labour mobility between sectors (Maloney 1999, Maloney 2004, Boschand Maloney 2007, Bosch and Maloney 2008). <strong>The</strong>y note that <strong>in</strong>formal employmentis a desirable choice (see Marcouiller et al. 1997, Maloney 1999) and see the <strong>in</strong>formalsector as a result <strong>of</strong> competitive markets <strong>in</strong> which <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>work</strong> voluntarilybecause <strong>of</strong> high opportunity costs, such as more exibility and avoidance <strong>of</strong> tax payments.<strong>The</strong> segmented market hypothesis is commonly rejected for Mexico.Another notable study is Meng (2001) which is one <strong>of</strong> the few studies whichdist<strong>in</strong>guish formal and <strong>in</strong>formal labour and <strong>in</strong>vestigate <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> migration <strong>in</strong> thesame context. For Ch<strong>in</strong>a, she nds that <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> raises the probability<strong>of</strong> becom<strong>in</strong>g a formal <strong>work</strong>er and that <strong>wage</strong> dierences are ma<strong>in</strong>ly expla<strong>in</strong>ed byobservable personal endowments.One drawback <strong>in</strong> the literature on <strong>in</strong>formal labour markets is the dierent denitions<strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>formality, which impede the comparison <strong>of</strong> the results. Generally, the mostcommonly used denitions can be classied <strong>in</strong>to two groups. First, the legalistic denitionis based on the contribution to the social security system (e.g. Tannuri-Piantoand Pianto 2002, Bosch and Maloney 2007, Bosch and Maloney 2008). Informal<strong>work</strong>ers are those, who do not contribute to the social security system and, synchronously,do not benet from social security regulations such as health care andpension schemes. Another legalistic denition is based on the formality <strong>of</strong> the <strong>work</strong>ers'contracts. Here, <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers are those, who do not have a written contractand, consequently, cannot assert their labour rights. However, they may enjoy moreexibility. <strong>The</strong> other group <strong>of</strong> denitions is based on productivity grounds. Accord<strong>in</strong>gto them, the <strong>in</strong>formal sector comprises <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> rms with less than or equal to veemployees (e.g. Maloney 1999, Gong and van Soest 2002), based on the argumentthat small rms tend neither to register their bus<strong>in</strong>ess nor their employees. <strong>The</strong>problem with rm size as a measure is that larger rms tend to pay higher <strong>wage</strong>s andare at risk <strong>of</strong> be<strong>in</strong>g caught default<strong>in</strong>g as their number <strong>of</strong> employees <strong>in</strong>creases. Hence,they are more likely to register (Badaoui, Strobl and Walsh 2007). In this studythe most unambiguous, legalistic, denition is used which corresponds to registrationwith the social security system.All articles found <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>tensive literature search and cited here for Mexico arebased on either <strong>rural</strong> or <strong>urban</strong> household surveys or solely on migrants. Us<strong>in</strong>g thenovel Mexican Family Life Survey allows the <strong>in</strong>vestigation <strong>of</strong> <strong>wage</strong> dierentials between<strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> dierent sectors. Notably, households from <strong>rural</strong>areas are more likely to be exposed to poverty and low (formal) employment opportunitiesand the likelihood for <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formal is higher <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas compared to<strong>urban</strong> areas.6


3 Empirical Methodology<strong>The</strong> empirical strategy to identify the determ<strong>in</strong>ants <strong>of</strong> the <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> dierentialand to nd out which <strong>wage</strong> related factors are ma<strong>in</strong>ly driv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rural</strong>-to-<strong>urban</strong>migration is to estimate <strong>wage</strong> regressions and to apply Bl<strong>in</strong>der-Oaxaca decompositiontechniques.One issue that has to be taken <strong>in</strong>to account when estimat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>wage</strong> equations fordierent groups <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers is dierent sources <strong>of</strong> selection bias. <strong>The</strong> most obvioussource is the selection bias from self-selection <strong>in</strong>to <strong>work</strong> vs. not <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g. <strong>The</strong> othersource is, given that an <strong>in</strong>dividual is <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g, self-selection <strong>in</strong>to one sector <strong>of</strong> thelabour market, dist<strong>in</strong>guish<strong>in</strong>g between formal salaried employment, <strong>in</strong>formal salariedemployment and self-employment 3 . As the self-employed have a very dierent <strong>wage</strong>determ<strong>in</strong>ation compared to salaried <strong>work</strong>ers, they are excluded from the sample 4 .Hence, the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g sectors are formal salaried employment and <strong>in</strong>formal salariedemployment.To account for selection bias, Heckman (1979) selection models are estimated.This two-step model is described <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g example for the self-selection <strong>in</strong>to<strong>work</strong>-bias correction. First, a probit model is estimated to determ<strong>in</strong>e the probability<strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual i <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g (w i = 1) as opposed to not <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g (w i = 0) which can bewritten as:w i = γZ i + u i (1)where Z i are observed characteristics <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dividual, such as human capital andfamily <strong>in</strong>dicators, γ is the vector <strong>of</strong> coecients <strong>of</strong> these variables and u i is the errorterm which is normally distributed with zero mean and unity variance. Subsequently,the nonselection hazard (also known as <strong>in</strong>verted Mill's ratio) λ w/nw is calculated fromthe estimated parameters <strong>of</strong> the selection equation. This is <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the secondstep <strong>wage</strong> regression which has the follow<strong>in</strong>g formln y i = α i + βX i + δλ w/nw + ɛ i (2)where y i is the hourly <strong>wage</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual i, β is a vector <strong>of</strong> coecients <strong>of</strong> observablepersonal and household characteristics X i and ɛ i the error term which is assumed tobe normally distributed with zero mean and variance σ 2 . y i is observed if and onlyif γZ i + u i > 0, i.e. w i > 0. <strong>The</strong> <strong>wage</strong> equations will be estimated both us<strong>in</strong>g ordi-3 See Magnac (1991) for evidence <strong>of</strong> self-selection <strong>in</strong>to the <strong>in</strong>formal sector.4 See Hamilton (2000) for a discussion on the diculty <strong>of</strong> measur<strong>in</strong>g self-employed earn<strong>in</strong>gs.7


nary least squares (OLS) and with the two-step method <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the nonselectionhazard term. <strong>The</strong> estimation results suggest that there is no self-selection <strong>in</strong>to <strong>work</strong>as the nonselection hazard coecient is <strong>in</strong>signicant and the other coecients donot dier between OLS and Heckman two-step. Hence, we do not need to accountfor self-selection <strong>in</strong>to <strong>work</strong> but only for self-selection <strong>in</strong>to formal employment whenestimat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>wage</strong> equations for formal and <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers separately. Hence, weonly <strong>in</strong>clude the selection bias correction term λ f/<strong>in</strong>f generated from a probit model<strong>in</strong> which the dependent variable is a dummy for <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g formally as opposed to<strong>in</strong>formally and vice versa for the other group.Subsequently, the two-fold Bl<strong>in</strong>der-Oaxaca decomposition technique (Bl<strong>in</strong>der 1973,Oaxaca 1973) is used to nd out <strong>in</strong> how far dierences <strong>in</strong> <strong>wage</strong>s between <strong>rural</strong> and<strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers are expla<strong>in</strong>ed by dierences <strong>in</strong> observable characteristics and to whichpart dierences rema<strong>in</strong> unexpla<strong>in</strong>ed. <strong>The</strong> decomposition technique can be written asln y R − ln y U = ˆβ R (X R − X U ) + ( ˆβ R − ˆβ ∗ )X R + ( ˆβ ∗ − ˆβ U )X U (3)where ˆβ U and ˆβ R are recovered from the separate <strong>wage</strong> equations <strong>of</strong> the <strong>rural</strong> and<strong>urban</strong> samples. β ∗ is a vector <strong>of</strong> coecients from a pooled model over both sampleswhich <strong>in</strong>cludes a dummy variables which identies the populations. <strong>The</strong> left handside <strong>of</strong> equation (3) is the raw <strong>wage</strong> gap, the right hand side consists <strong>of</strong> the dierence<strong>in</strong> characteristics or expla<strong>in</strong>ed part and the unexpla<strong>in</strong>ed part due to dierences <strong>in</strong>coecients. To determ<strong>in</strong>e the expla<strong>in</strong>ed part the group dierences <strong>in</strong> the endowmentsvector is weighted by the coecients vector <strong>of</strong> the <strong>rural</strong> population. To identify thecontribution <strong>of</strong> the human capital variables separately, we decompose the <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong><strong>wage</strong> dierential <strong>in</strong> detail.4 Data<strong>The</strong> data used is the novel Mexican Family Life Survey (MxFLS) which is a panelsurvey <strong>of</strong> approximately 8,440 Mexican households and 35,000 <strong>in</strong>dividuals. It isrepresentative at the regional, <strong>urban</strong>-<strong>rural</strong> and state levels and conta<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>formationon the <strong>in</strong>dividuals, households and communities with a re-contact rate between therst wave <strong>in</strong> 2002 (MxFLS-1) and the second wave <strong>of</strong> 2005 (MxFLS-2) <strong>of</strong> about90%. <strong>The</strong> questions cover a variety <strong>of</strong> topics such as labour market status, familycharacteristics, education, household <strong>in</strong>come, health and self-evaluations. 5This study uses exclusively the second wave (MxFLS-2) because earn<strong>in</strong>gs variables5 More details can be found at http://www.ennvih-mxs.org/.8


Table 1: Distribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividuals by sectorsUrbanRuralMean Std.Dev. Mean Std.Dev.Not <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g 0.51 (0.50) 0.63 (0.48)Informal salaried 0.30 (0.46) 0.29 (0.45)Formal salaried 0.19 (0.39) 0.08 (0.27)N 6358 4500Note: Authours' calculations based on MxFLS-2.seem less reliable <strong>in</strong> 2002. 6<strong>The</strong> data is restricted to men and women between theage <strong>of</strong> 16 and 65 years. Self-employed <strong>work</strong>ers, full-time students and the seriouslyill (<strong>in</strong>capable) are excluded from the sample. <strong>The</strong> nal sample consists <strong>of</strong> almost11,000 <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>of</strong> whom 44% are salaried <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> either formal or <strong>in</strong>formalemployment. <strong>The</strong> detailed distribution <strong>of</strong> the <strong>work</strong>force is displayed <strong>in</strong> Table 1. <strong>The</strong>not employed <strong>in</strong>clude also <strong>work</strong>ers without remuneration. In the <strong>rural</strong> areas 37%(29% + 8%) are salaried <strong>work</strong>ers. In <strong>urban</strong> areas 49% (30% + 19%) are employed.Individuals were dened as liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a <strong>rural</strong> area if they live <strong>in</strong> a community with lessthan 2500 <strong>in</strong>habitants, and <strong>in</strong> an <strong>urban</strong> area otherwise.<strong>The</strong>re are dierent denitions <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>formality <strong>in</strong> the literature, be<strong>in</strong>g based <strong>in</strong> rmsize, contracts or occupations.<strong>The</strong> here used legalistic denition <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formalsector is based on the denition <strong>of</strong> Mexico's Federal Labour Law, which dist<strong>in</strong>guishessalaried and non-salaried <strong>work</strong>ers by employer or rm dependency. With<strong>in</strong> this denitionthe number <strong>of</strong> subgroups is large and assign<strong>in</strong>g occupations to certa<strong>in</strong> groupsis not possible as the majority <strong>of</strong> jobs can be salaried and non-salaried. One examplethat is given by Levy (2008) is a shoe sh<strong>in</strong>er who can <strong>work</strong> <strong>in</strong>dependently and also hecould be employed by a hotel be<strong>in</strong>g a salaried <strong>work</strong>er. Salaried <strong>work</strong>ers are eligible tosocial security benets which <strong>in</strong>clude health <strong>in</strong>surance, pension, child care, hous<strong>in</strong>gloans, life and <strong>work</strong>-risk <strong>in</strong>surance and sports and cultural facilities, when they areregistered with the IMSS (Insitituto Mexicano del Seguro Social). Moreover, theyare protected by r<strong>in</strong>g regulations and severance pay.In fact, Social Security Law prescribes that salaried <strong>work</strong>ers must be registered bytheir employers with the IMSS. <strong>The</strong> denition <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>formality based on enroll<strong>in</strong>g withIMSS is most relevant and accurate for Mexico because <strong>of</strong> the legal labour market <strong>in</strong>stitutionsas expla<strong>in</strong>ed by Levy (2008). Hence, <strong>in</strong>formation on the <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g contracts6 In 2002 about 20% <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers stated non-positive <strong>wage</strong>s while no <strong>in</strong>dividual stated non-positive<strong>wage</strong>s <strong>in</strong> 2005. <strong>The</strong> reasons for this may not be due to idiosyncratic measurement error.9


is used to dene <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers 7 . This classies those <strong>in</strong>dividuals as <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>erswho do not have an ISSSTE-contract (government <strong>work</strong>ers) or an IMSS-contract(registered to social security) and formal if they have either. <strong>The</strong> ISSSTE is the socialsecurity <strong>in</strong>stitution for public sector <strong>work</strong>ers and the armed forces. As not all public<strong>work</strong>ers are registered with ISSSTE, e.g. public <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> educational <strong>in</strong>stitutionsand <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>of</strong> the public electricity companies, it is impossible to exclude all public<strong>work</strong>ers and hence they form the group <strong>of</strong> formal <strong>work</strong>ers together with all <strong>work</strong>erswho are registered with IMSS. This legalistic denition is also used by e.g. Boschand Maloney (2007) and Barga<strong>in</strong> and Kwenda (2009).Figure 3: Wage Distribution<strong>The</strong> key dependent variable is log hourly <strong>wage</strong> which is constructed by divid<strong>in</strong>greported average monthly earn<strong>in</strong>gs by 4.33 times reported average hours <strong>work</strong>ed perweek. Individuals who failed to report positive <strong>wage</strong>s were deleted from the sample,account<strong>in</strong>g for about 2%. Additionally, the top and the bottom two percentiles <strong>of</strong> the<strong>wage</strong> distribution were deleted from the sample to avoid bias due to outliers. Figure3 shows the mean <strong>of</strong> hourly log <strong>wage</strong>s <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> the dierent groups. It can easilybe seen that formal <strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong>s are highest on average and <strong>rural</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>wage</strong>sare lowest.Formal <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers have about the same mean<strong>wage</strong>. Figure 4 plots hourly <strong>wage</strong>s for all groups separately on years <strong>of</strong> school<strong>in</strong>g and<strong>experience</strong>, respectively. It can be seen that <strong>wage</strong>s dier with regard to school<strong>in</strong>gfor the highest educational groups as can be expected, with lowest <strong>wage</strong>s for <strong>rural</strong><strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers and highest for <strong>urban</strong> formal <strong>work</strong>ers. <strong>The</strong> graph for <strong>experience</strong>shows a greater dierence between the groups. <strong>The</strong>se patterns will be more preciselyanalysed <strong>in</strong> the next section.7 As Maloney (1998), Bosch and Maloney (2008) and Levy (2008) po<strong>in</strong>t out, <strong>work</strong>ers, especiallypoor <strong>work</strong>ers, are highly mobile between sectors and hence <strong>work</strong>ers can actually not be labelledas formal <strong>work</strong>ers or <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers. For simplicity we use these terms here but actually, whenreferr<strong>in</strong>g to an <strong>in</strong>formal (formal) <strong>work</strong>er, we mean an <strong>in</strong>dividual, who's last job at the time <strong>of</strong> datacollection has been <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal (formal) sector.10


Figure 4: Wage Distribution<strong>The</strong> key <strong>in</strong>dependent variables are <strong>experience</strong>, education, cognitive ability andfamily and job characteristics. Experience is modelled as M<strong>in</strong>cerian potential <strong>experience</strong>(age m<strong>in</strong>us years <strong>of</strong> school<strong>in</strong>g m<strong>in</strong>us 6) because job history is not available<strong>in</strong> the data. <strong>The</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividuals are divided <strong>in</strong>to two education groups, i.e. educationup to compulsory level (0-9 years <strong>of</strong> school<strong>in</strong>g) or more (≥10 years), <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g highschool and university graduates. A special feature <strong>of</strong> the MxFLS is that a Raven'stest was conducted with almost every <strong>in</strong>dividual. <strong>The</strong> Raven's test scores measurean <strong>in</strong>dividual's cognitive ability and the test scores are <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the regressions 8 .In the returns to education literature it is argued that an <strong>in</strong>dividual's educationalachievement is <strong>in</strong>uenced by their <strong>in</strong>telligence and the <strong>in</strong>clusion would lead to endogeneitybias (Card 1999, Psacharopoulos 1994). However, the correlation coecientbetween the years <strong>of</strong> education and the test score is 0.33 suggest<strong>in</strong>g that endogeneityproblems can be neglected. <strong>The</strong> <strong>in</strong>clusion <strong>of</strong> the test score should only lower theeducation estimates.Family characteristics <strong>in</strong>clude household size, number <strong>of</strong> elderly and <strong>in</strong>fants <strong>in</strong>the household, dummies for be<strong>in</strong>g the household head, be<strong>in</strong>g married and a measure<strong>of</strong> other household earn<strong>in</strong>gs per head if the regarded <strong>in</strong>dividual did not <strong>work</strong>. Thisvariable is theoretically a measure <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>centive to <strong>work</strong> or <strong>work</strong> <strong>in</strong> a formal job:if the potential <strong>in</strong>come exclud<strong>in</strong>g one' own <strong>in</strong>come is high, the <strong>in</strong>centive to apply forand <strong>work</strong> <strong>in</strong> a formal job might be exceeded by <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>formal job because <strong>of</strong>opportunity costs (e.g. bureaucracy, taxes and lack <strong>of</strong> exibility). On the other hand,the <strong>in</strong>centive might decrease with <strong>in</strong>come as shown for men <strong>in</strong> Gong and van Soest(2002). For women, the authors nd that the probability <strong>of</strong> not <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>creaseswith the <strong>in</strong>come <strong>of</strong> other family members. This variable along with household debtsand household non-labour <strong>in</strong>come are serv<strong>in</strong>g as selection variables <strong>in</strong> the probit8 see Raven, Raven and Court (1998, updated 2003) for more <strong>in</strong>formation about the test.11


Table 2: Descriptive statistics by sector and localityInformalFormalUrban Rural Urban RuralMean SD Mean SD Mean SD Mean SDFemale 0.35 (0.48) 0.24 (0.43) 0.37 (0.48) 0.28 (0.45)Married 0.44 (0.50) 0.44 (0.50) 0.55 (0.50) 0.52 (0.50)Indigenous 0.07 (0.26) 0.17 (0.38) 0.06 (0.24) 0.13 (0.33)Hh head 0.40 (0.49) 0.43 (0.50) 0.46 (0.50) 0.46 (0.50)High education 0.32 (0.47) 0.14 (0.34) 0.47 (0.50) 0.32 (0.47)Age 16-25 0.35 (0.48) 0.37 (0.48) 0.23 (0.42) 0.28 (0.45)Age 26-35 0.24 (0.43) 0.23 (0.42) 0.31 (0.46) 0.28 (0.45)Age 36-45 0.21 (0.41) 0.21 (0.41) 0.26 (0.44) 0.22 (0.41)Age >46 0.2 (0.4) 0.2 (0.4) 0.2 (0.4) 0.2 (0.4)Experience 18.68 (13.94) 20.88 (14.83) 19.04 (11.89) 20.13 (13.45)Raven test 0.6 (0.23) 0.5 (0.24) 0.6 (0.23) 0.5 (0.23)Hh size 10.1 (4.59) 10.9 (5.02) 9.3 (4.09) 10.0 (4.05)Nr. <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>fants <strong>in</strong> hh 0.4 (0.64) 0.4 (0.62) 0.3 (0.58) 0.3 (0.63)Nr. <strong>of</strong> elderly <strong>in</strong> hh 0.34 (0.9) 0.41 (0.9) 0.31 (0.8) 0.44 (1.0)Other hh earn<strong>in</strong>gs 20.15 (29.77) 13.31 (22.25) 22.91 (35.45) 16.83 (22.99)Log(hh debts) 2.03 (3.17) 1.40 (2.63) 2.47 (3.50) 1.64 (2.97)Log(hh non-labour i) 0.46 (1.7) 0.36 (1.5) 0.62 (2.0) 0.45 (1.7)Farm 0.1 (0.24) 0.2 (0.41) 0.0 (0.17) 0.2 (0.41)N 1917 1295 1206 365Note: Authors' calculations based on MxFLS-2. Numbers are mean values and standard deviations<strong>in</strong> parentheses.models.Table 2 provides descriptive statistics on these variables. It can be seen that theaverage years <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> are higher <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas than <strong>in</strong> <strong>urban</strong> areas. Thispattern is very similar <strong>in</strong> the formal and the <strong>in</strong>formal sector with about 20-21 years<strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> and about 19 years <strong>in</strong> <strong>urban</strong> areas. It appears that the dierences <strong>in</strong> years <strong>of</strong><strong>experience</strong> are driven by dierences <strong>in</strong> education and are not due to age dierencesas the age p<strong>role</strong>s do not dier largely between <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> residents. Years <strong>of</strong><strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> are highly correlated with age because we can only use potential<strong>experience</strong>. After discuss<strong>in</strong>g the ma<strong>in</strong> results, we will also discuss some robustnesschecks which show that the results for returns to <strong>experience</strong> dier from those for age.Notably, the share <strong>of</strong> high educated <strong>work</strong>ers is very dierent between sectors.<strong>The</strong> highest share <strong>of</strong> high educated <strong>work</strong>ers is <strong>in</strong> the <strong>urban</strong> formal sector with 47%<strong>of</strong> all <strong>work</strong>ers. In the <strong>urban</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal sector, 32% are university educated as well as<strong>in</strong> the formal <strong>rural</strong> sector and only 13% <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> the <strong>rural</strong> areashave attended high school and/or university or college. Furthermore, the <strong>urban</strong><strong>work</strong>force performs better <strong>in</strong> the Raven's test score. <strong>The</strong>se observations h<strong>in</strong>t at the12


existence <strong>of</strong> self-selection <strong>in</strong>to formal employment <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> areas based onhuman capital endowments. Also, dierences between <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers existwith regard to nancial household <strong>in</strong>dicators such as the average other householdmembers' <strong>in</strong>come which is 55% higher for <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers than for <strong>rural</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong>the <strong>in</strong>formal sector and 40% higher for <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers than for <strong>rural</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> theformal sector. Interest<strong>in</strong>gly, household debts are on average higher for <strong>urban</strong> thanfor <strong>rural</strong> households.5 Results5.1 All <strong>work</strong>ersWe beg<strong>in</strong> by describ<strong>in</strong>g the self-selection <strong>in</strong>to <strong>work</strong> results from the probit estimationswhich can be found <strong>in</strong> Appendix Table A1. As expected, hav<strong>in</strong>g a university degreeand a high score <strong>in</strong> Raven's test <strong>in</strong>creases the probability <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> salariedemployment as compared to not <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g or not be<strong>in</strong>g remunerated. Belong<strong>in</strong>g to an<strong>in</strong>digenous group does not <strong>in</strong>uence the decision or possibility to <strong>work</strong>, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>gthat discrim<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>digenous people is not a severe problem <strong>in</strong> the Mexicanlabour market. Furthermore, age <strong>in</strong>creases the probability <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g salaried asopposed to not <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g. Moreover, the female dummy is negative and signicant aswe expect because females are less likely to <strong>work</strong> than men. On the household side,several characteristics seem to be important <strong>in</strong> the determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> the selectionprocess. <strong>The</strong> average other household <strong>in</strong>come m<strong>in</strong>us the <strong>in</strong>dividual's <strong>in</strong>come andhousehold debts signicantly <strong>in</strong>crease the probability <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g and a higher number<strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>fants <strong>in</strong> the household decreases the probability <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g. All <strong>in</strong> all, there aresignicant determ<strong>in</strong>ants <strong>of</strong> employment and no large dierences between <strong>rural</strong> and<strong>urban</strong> location.<strong>The</strong> <strong>wage</strong> regressions which <strong>in</strong>clude the nonselection hazard term generated fromthe probit estimations show that self-selection <strong>in</strong>to salaried employment does notaect the <strong>wage</strong> determ<strong>in</strong>ation neither <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> nor <strong>in</strong> <strong>urban</strong> areas (Table 3) and it canbe concluded that the <strong>wage</strong> regression results are not biased due to self-selection <strong>in</strong>to<strong>work</strong>. Hence, <strong>in</strong> the subsequent <strong>wage</strong> regressions for formal and <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers, itis not necessary to control for self-selection <strong>in</strong>to <strong>work</strong> which allows a relatively simpleestimation procedure. In the follow<strong>in</strong>g, we will base our discussion on the Heckmantwo-step estimation results. At this po<strong>in</strong>t it has to be made clear, that althoughthe <strong>wage</strong> regressions are based on cross-sections, unobserved ability bias is reduceddue to the Raven's test score variable. Interest<strong>in</strong>gly, the test score coecient is onlysignicant for <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers and suggests that by answer<strong>in</strong>g one more <strong>of</strong> the twelvequestions correctly raises the <strong>wage</strong> on average by 12 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts.13


In the <strong>wage</strong> regression for the whole sample (column 2), it can be seen that asignicant <strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> premium exists and amounts to about 17%. This nd<strong>in</strong>g isvery similar to the results <strong>of</strong> Glaeser and Maré (2001). <strong>The</strong> <strong>wage</strong> regression for all<strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> the sample is extended by <strong>in</strong>teraction terms <strong>of</strong> the human capital variableswith the <strong>urban</strong> residence dummy. Only the <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> <strong>in</strong>teraction coecientsare signicant and suggest that <strong>experience</strong> has a higher reward <strong>in</strong> <strong>urban</strong> areas than<strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas. <strong>The</strong>se nd<strong>in</strong>gs are further supported by the separate <strong>wage</strong> equationsfor <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers (columns 5-8). While the return to one additional year<strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> is 2.1% <strong>in</strong> <strong>urban</strong> areas, it is not signicantly dierent from zero <strong>in</strong><strong>rural</strong> areas. This nd<strong>in</strong>g is important because higher rewards for <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> <strong>in</strong><strong>urban</strong> areas will play a <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> the decision to stay <strong>in</strong> an <strong>urban</strong> area if they live thereor to migrate to a city if they are currently liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the countryside. However, thecoecients cannot be compared quantitatively as they were estimated <strong>in</strong> separateregressions. To see if <strong>experience</strong> is <strong>in</strong>deed such an important factor <strong>in</strong> expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the<strong>wage</strong> dierential, detailed decomposition analyses will be applied. Before we come tothese results, we will discuss the nd<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>of</strong> the formal/<strong>in</strong>formal sector <strong>wage</strong> analyses.5.2 Formal vs. <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ersAs mentioned <strong>in</strong> the literature section, several authors have found <strong>wage</strong> dierentialsbetween formal and <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers. We show that this dierential also exists <strong>in</strong>2005 <strong>in</strong> Mexico, even when dist<strong>in</strong>guish<strong>in</strong>g between <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers. Thatthe dierential also exists <strong>in</strong> the <strong>rural</strong> areas <strong>of</strong> 11% and 9% <strong>in</strong> the cities (Table 3,columns 6 and 8) is novel evidence because earlier studies on the formal <strong>wage</strong> gap<strong>in</strong> Mexico were ma<strong>in</strong>ly based on the National Urban Employment Survey which didnot cover <strong>rural</strong> households.To avoid bias from self-selection <strong>in</strong>to formal employment probit regressions wereconducted for all, <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers separately. <strong>The</strong> results can be found<strong>in</strong> Appendix Table A2. It can be seen that chang<strong>in</strong>g residence from <strong>rural</strong> to <strong>urban</strong><strong>in</strong>creases a <strong>work</strong>er's probability <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g formally as opposed to <strong>in</strong>formally by 13%-po<strong>in</strong>ts, which can be expected when tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account that only 22% <strong>of</strong> all <strong>work</strong>ers<strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas but 39% <strong>of</strong> all <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers are formally employed. <strong>The</strong> separateprobit equations for <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers show that determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> formal employmentdiers between <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> employees with respect to cognitive ability,other household earn<strong>in</strong>gs and household size. For example, <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas, scor<strong>in</strong>ghigh <strong>in</strong> Raven's test raises the probability <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g formally by 12%-po<strong>in</strong>ts andis <strong>in</strong>signicantly dierent from zero <strong>in</strong> <strong>urban</strong> areas. Also, the larger the household,the less likely a <strong>work</strong>er is formally employed <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas, but there is no eect for<strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers.14


Table 3: Wage equations for all, <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ersAll Rural UrbanOLS Heck OLS Heck OLS Heck OLS HeckUrban 0.164 ∗∗∗ 0.174 ∗∗∗ 0.020 0.027 − − − −(0.022) (0.025) (0.073) (0.075)Exp*Urban − − 0.009 ∗ 0.009 ∗ − − − −(0.005) (0.005)Exp sq.*Urban − − -0.010 -0.010 − − − −(0.009) (0.009)High edu.*Urban − − 0.049 0.048 − − − −(0.051) (0.051)Raven*Urban − − 0.022 0.022 − − − −(0.085) (0.084)Experience 0.015 ∗∗∗ 0.016 ∗∗∗ 0.008 ∗∗ 0.009 ∗∗ 0.004 0.002 0.017 ∗∗∗ 0.021 ∗∗∗(0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.005) (0.004) (0.005) (0.003) (0.004)Experience sq/100 -0.029 ∗∗∗ -0.032 ∗∗∗ -0.021 ∗∗∗ -0.023 ∗∗∗ -0.016 ∗∗ -0.011 -0.030 ∗∗∗ -0.037 ∗∗∗(0.005) (0.006) (0.007) (0.009) (0.008) (0.010) (0.006) (0.008)High education 0.230 ∗∗∗ 0.245 ∗∗∗ 0.198 ∗∗∗ 0.205 ∗∗∗ 0.170 ∗∗∗ 0.152 ∗∗∗ 0.236 ∗∗∗ 0.268 ∗∗∗(0.026) (0.031) (0.046) (0.050) (0.054) (0.059) (0.030) (0.037)Raven test 0.109 ∗∗∗ 0.115 ∗∗∗ 0.092 0.095 0.057 0.045 0.107 ∗∗ 0.117 ∗∗(0.041) (0.041) (0.067) (0.067) (0.071) (0.072) (0.051) (0.052)HH size -0.003 -0.002 -0.003 -0.003 0.004 0.003 -0.007 ∗∗ -0.005 ∗(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.003)Indigenous -0.056 ∗ -0.058 ∗ -0.055 ∗ -0.056 ∗ -0.085 ∗ -0.083 ∗ -0.017 -0.023(0.033) (0.033) (0.033) (0.033) (0.048) (0.047) (0.047) (0.047)Female -0.090 ∗∗∗ -0.144 ∗∗ -0.091 ∗∗∗ -0.113 ∗ -0.076 0.026 -0.095 ∗∗∗ -0.184 ∗∗∗(0.026) (0.065) (0.026) (0.066) (0.049) (0.149) (0.031) (0.071)HH head 0.011 0.035 0.011 0.021 0.079 ∗ 0.043 -0.007 0.042(0.026) (0.037) (0.026) (0.037) (0.044) (0.066) (0.032) (0.047)Married 0.082 ∗∗∗ 0.067 ∗∗ 0.083 ∗∗∗ 0.077 ∗∗∗ 0.039 0.060 0.095 ∗∗∗ 0.064 ∗(0.021) (0.027) (0.021) (0.027) (0.039) (0.048) (0.026) (0.034)Formal 0.098 ∗∗∗ 0.098 ∗∗∗ 0.097 ∗∗∗ 0.097 ∗∗∗ 0.114 ∗∗ 0.112 ∗∗∗ 0.085 ∗∗∗ 0.085 ∗∗∗(0.022) (0.022) (0.022) (0.022) (0.044) (0.044) (0.025) (0.025)Constant 2.844 ∗∗∗ 2.786 ∗∗∗ 2.947 ∗∗∗ 2.921 ∗∗∗ 2.850 ∗∗∗ 2.921 ∗∗∗ 3.055 ∗∗∗ 2.951 ∗∗∗(0.091) (0.110) (0.102) (0.123) (0.161) (0.186) (0.127) (0.146)λ w/nw − 0.069 − 0.028 − -0.101 − 0.133(0.076) (0.077) (0.139) (0.095)State dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesIndustry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesOccup. dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesN 4813 10880 4813 10880 1660 4495 3153 6385¯R 2 0.296 − 0.297 − 0.210 − 0.301 −χ 2 − 2048 − 2065 − 515 − 1404p 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Note: Standard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses. ∗ , ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ denote signicance level <strong>of</strong> 1%, 5% and 10% respcetively.OLS: Ord<strong>in</strong>ary Least Squares, Heck: Heckman Selection 2nd step. 15 state dummies, 23 <strong>in</strong>dustry dummies and18 occupation dummies <strong>in</strong>cluded. λ is the nonselection hazard variable generated from the probit model.15


<strong>The</strong> results <strong>of</strong> the separate <strong>wage</strong> equations for formal and <strong>in</strong>formal sector <strong>work</strong>erssupport what we have found <strong>in</strong> the <strong>wage</strong> equation for all <strong>work</strong>ers but suggestquantitative dierences between the sectors. <strong>The</strong> tables are <strong>in</strong> the appendix (TablesA3 and A4). For both formal and <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers no self-selection is distort<strong>in</strong>g theresults, because <strong>in</strong> all regressions the nonselection hazard coecient is <strong>in</strong>signicant.From the regression for <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers we can see that a signicant <strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong>premium exists, which is further supported by the separate equations (columns 6 and8). We also nd a signicant return to high education <strong>of</strong> about 17% <strong>in</strong> the <strong>rural</strong> and22% <strong>in</strong> the <strong>urban</strong> areas. For <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers there is no return to cognitive abilityas the coecient is not signicantly dierent from zero.Figure 5: Returns to <strong>experience</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal sectorFor formal <strong>work</strong>ers, the results suggest that human capital is not rewarded <strong>in</strong><strong>rural</strong> areas because the coecients are not signicantly dierent from zero. Urbanformal <strong>work</strong>ers have signicant large returns to education (27%) and a return to years<strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> <strong>of</strong> 1.5%. <strong>The</strong> <strong>in</strong>teraction terms <strong>of</strong> the human capital variableswith the <strong>urban</strong> dummy are not signicant, suggest<strong>in</strong>g, that <strong>urban</strong> rms that registertheir <strong>work</strong>ers with IMSS do not pay higher rewards to human capital than their <strong>rural</strong>counterparts. Furthermore, the results show that it is important to separate the<strong>work</strong>force <strong>in</strong>to dierent groups when the <strong>in</strong>tention is to detect determ<strong>in</strong>ants <strong>of</strong> <strong>wage</strong><strong>in</strong>equality. We will decompose the <strong>wage</strong> dierential <strong>in</strong> the next section to uncoverwhich <strong>role</strong> the dierent <strong>in</strong>dicators <strong>of</strong> human capital play <strong>in</strong> the determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong><strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> dierentials.In essence, the results suggest that <strong>experience</strong> does not get rewarded <strong>in</strong> the <strong>rural</strong>areas. This will elevate the <strong>in</strong>centive to migrate to the <strong>urban</strong> areas. As a consequence,the <strong>in</strong>formal sector will <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>urban</strong> areas, assum<strong>in</strong>g that formal jobs do notemerge as quickly as the <strong>rural</strong> population migrates. To visualise the nd<strong>in</strong>gs, the16


Figure 6: Returns to <strong>experience</strong> <strong>in</strong> formal sectorcoecients <strong>of</strong> the returns to <strong>experience</strong> are plotted <strong>in</strong> Figures 5 and 6 for <strong>in</strong>formaland formal <strong>work</strong>ers, respectively. Note that the returns to <strong>experience</strong> are <strong>in</strong>signicantfor <strong>rural</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers but not for <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers.One observation that can be made from the results, although not the focus <strong>of</strong>our study, is that there is no <strong>wage</strong> penalty for <strong>work</strong>ers who belong to an <strong>in</strong>digenousgroup. This is a positive result as it suggests that discrim<strong>in</strong>ation aga<strong>in</strong>st <strong>in</strong>digenousgroups is not apparent <strong>in</strong> the Mexican labour market with respect to <strong>wage</strong>s and withrespect to employment as was seen <strong>in</strong> the probit estimations.5.3 Bl<strong>in</strong>der-Oaxaca DecompositionF<strong>in</strong>ally, the results from Bl<strong>in</strong>der-Oaxaca decomposition will be discussed. Table A5shows that the overall dierence between <strong>urban</strong> and <strong>rural</strong> <strong>wage</strong>s is 29% for <strong>in</strong>formal<strong>work</strong>ers and 26% for formal <strong>work</strong>ers. Almost half <strong>of</strong> the dierential can be expla<strong>in</strong>edby observable characteristics <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector and about one third <strong>in</strong> the formalsector. <strong>The</strong> detailed decomposition results are displayed <strong>in</strong> Table 4 for <strong>in</strong>formal andformal <strong>work</strong>ers, respectively. <strong>The</strong> results for <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ers show that dierences<strong>in</strong> education and cognitive ability endowments largely expla<strong>in</strong> the <strong>wage</strong> gap. Dierences<strong>in</strong> years <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> do not expla<strong>in</strong> the <strong>wage</strong> gap, however. When welook at the unexpla<strong>in</strong>ed part, it can be seen that dierences <strong>in</strong> coecients <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong>account for the largest share <strong>of</strong> the unexpla<strong>in</strong>ed part. Returns to educationand cognitive ability do not play a <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> the unexpla<strong>in</strong>ed part <strong>of</strong> the <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong><strong>wage</strong> dierential, nor do the returns or premia to other characteristics. Hence, thereare signicant dierences <strong>in</strong> returns to <strong>experience</strong>, even after controll<strong>in</strong>g for otherobservable characteristics and self-selection.In the formal sector, this dierence <strong>in</strong> coecients does not exist neither for ex-17


Table 4: Decomposition for <strong>in</strong>formal and formal <strong>work</strong>ersOLSHeckInformal Expla<strong>in</strong>ed Unexpla<strong>in</strong>ed Expla<strong>in</strong>ed Unexpla<strong>in</strong>edExperience -0.000 0.182*** 0.002 0.178**(0.003) (0.069) (0.004) (0.074)High education 0.039*** 0.004 0.038*** 0.004(0.007) (0.014) (0.007) (0.014)Raven test 0.005** 0.017 0.005** 0.018(0.003) (0.054) (0.003) (0.054)Other 0.082*** -0.038 0.079*** -0.033(0.018) (0.099) (0.018) (0.102)N 3249Formal Expla<strong>in</strong>ed Unexpla<strong>in</strong>ed Expla<strong>in</strong>ed Unexpla<strong>in</strong>edExperience 0.009* 0.174* 0.008 0.184(0.005) (0.095) (0.006) (0.125)High education 0.038*** 0.036 0.037*** 0.040(0.009) (0.036) (0.012) (0.057)Raven test 0.007 0.109 0.006 0.112(0.005) (0.085) (0.005) (0.089)Other 0.036 -0.143 0.038 -0.161(0.026) (0.152) (0.031) (0.217)N 1564Note: Standard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses. ∗ , ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ denote signicance level <strong>of</strong> 1%, 5% and 10% respcetively. OLS:Ord<strong>in</strong>ary Least Squares, Heck: Heckman Selection 2nd step. <strong>The</strong> decomposition is formulated from the viewpo<strong>in</strong>t<strong>of</strong> the <strong>rural</strong> population. For the underly<strong>in</strong>g regressions see <strong>wage</strong> regression tables. States <strong>in</strong>lcudes 15 statedummies, Work characteristics <strong>in</strong>cludes 23 <strong>in</strong>dustry dummies and 18 occupation dummies, Social characteristics<strong>in</strong>clude married, hh head, hh size, <strong>in</strong>digenous and a female dummy.18


perience nor for any other variable. Solely the dierence <strong>in</strong> average education is expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gthe <strong>wage</strong> gap <strong>in</strong> the formal sector as can be seen <strong>in</strong> Table 4. This shows thatit is not sucient estimat<strong>in</strong>g separate <strong>wage</strong> equations for <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers toidentify dierences <strong>in</strong> returns to endowments. This nd<strong>in</strong>g supports the hypothesisthat <strong>urban</strong> rms are more human capital <strong>in</strong>tensive and high education is important<strong>in</strong> those rms.5.4 Robustness checksWe conduct a series <strong>of</strong> robustness checks to make sure that <strong>in</strong>consistencies <strong>in</strong> thedata set do not drive the results and that we did not oversee important dierencesbetween groups, such as between men and women. Hence, we estimate the regressionsfor men and women separately and nd no signicant gender dierences regard<strong>in</strong>gthe ma<strong>in</strong> result, i.e. for both males and females, the return to <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> ishigher <strong>in</strong> <strong>urban</strong> areas than <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas and this expla<strong>in</strong>s the largest share <strong>of</strong> theunexpla<strong>in</strong>ed part <strong>in</strong> the <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> dierential. Furthermore, all regressions arerun <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g a dierent education variable, which is equal to one if the <strong>in</strong>dividualshas atta<strong>in</strong>ed university and equal to zero if educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment was up to highschool level. In all regressions, the coecient was larger and still signicant but notchang<strong>in</strong>g the results qualitatively.One drawback <strong>of</strong> the data is that we cannot measure actual <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> as wedo not have sucient <strong>in</strong>formation on job history. As <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> is measured byage m<strong>in</strong>us years <strong>of</strong> education m<strong>in</strong>us 6, the correlation between our <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong>variable and age is high (about 97%). To remedy the concern that we are not actuallymeasur<strong>in</strong>g the eects <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> but the returns to age, we plotted <strong>wage</strong>s onyears <strong>of</strong> age <strong>in</strong> Figure 7. Compar<strong>in</strong>g the plots with those on <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> it canbe seen that there are dierences <strong>in</strong> age and <strong>experience</strong> p<strong>role</strong>s.Figure 7: Wage Distribution, age <strong>in</strong>stead <strong>of</strong> exp19


In a follow<strong>in</strong>g step we estimated all regressions <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g age <strong>in</strong>stead <strong>of</strong> <strong>experience</strong>.<strong>The</strong> coecients are larger for age than for <strong>experience</strong> and there are no signicantdierences between <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers. Hence, it can be concluded, that our<strong>experience</strong> variable is actually measur<strong>in</strong>g the eect <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> and not that<strong>of</strong> age. Moreover, all <strong>wage</strong> equations were also estimated <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g a cubic term <strong>of</strong><strong>experience</strong> and with <strong>experience</strong> only. For some groups <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers, the coecientswere also signicant but the nd<strong>in</strong>gs do not dier qualitatively from the discussedresults. 95.5 Discussion<strong>The</strong> nd<strong>in</strong>gs provide evidence that <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> dierentials exist <strong>in</strong> Mexicoand that there are dierences <strong>in</strong> the decomposition between <strong>in</strong> formal and <strong>in</strong>formal<strong>work</strong>ers. Denitely, dierences <strong>in</strong> all human capital related factors expla<strong>in</strong> a largepart <strong>of</strong> the <strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> gap <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector, while only education expla<strong>in</strong>spart <strong>of</strong> the <strong>wage</strong> gap <strong>in</strong> the formal sector. Additionally, <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector, returnsto <strong>experience</strong> are much lower for <strong>rural</strong> than for <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers, even after controll<strong>in</strong>gfor a large number <strong>of</strong> observable characteristics. When consider<strong>in</strong>g that only a smallpart <strong>of</strong> the formal sector resides <strong>in</strong> the <strong>rural</strong> areas and <strong>wage</strong>s are signicantly lower<strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas, small returns to <strong>experience</strong> are denitely a push factor out <strong>of</strong> the <strong>rural</strong>and <strong>in</strong>to the <strong>urban</strong> labour market, seem<strong>in</strong>gly preferably and possibly easier <strong>in</strong>to the<strong>in</strong>formal sector when the <strong>in</strong>dividual is endowed with at least some years <strong>of</strong> <strong>experience</strong>.Furthermore, the results seem to expla<strong>in</strong>, at least partly, the macroeconomic picturedescribed <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>troduction. If the observed <strong>wage</strong> pattern cont<strong>in</strong>ues to exist, lowreturns to <strong>experience</strong> will not only act as a push factor away from <strong>rural</strong> areas and<strong>in</strong>to the cities but also serve as an impediment for return migration. This will havefurther consequences for the existence <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector. Assum<strong>in</strong>g that formaljobs do not emerge as quickly as the <strong>rural</strong> population migrates and the social securityprotection system does not change, the <strong>in</strong>formal sector and unemployment will further<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the cities.As we are able to control for a large number <strong>of</strong> personal characteristics, it is likelythat unobserved rm characteristics expla<strong>in</strong> parts <strong>of</strong> the <strong>wage</strong> dierential. As hasbeen shown by other authors, rms <strong>in</strong> the cities are more productive and hence theypay higher <strong>wage</strong>s (Glaeser and Maré 2001, Gould 2007). It seems plausible, that<strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> is only necessary <strong>in</strong> <strong>urban</strong> rms rather than <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> rms, which issupported by our results. This will be an <strong>in</strong>centive for <strong>in</strong>dividuals to migrate to thecities to accumulate human capital <strong>in</strong> the form <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> and be accord<strong>in</strong>gly9 <strong>The</strong> result tables <strong>of</strong> the robustness checks are not displayed for the sake <strong>of</strong> brevity but can besent on request by the correspond<strong>in</strong>g author.20


paid. This is also <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the theoretical suggestion by Lucas (2004).For policy makers, these nd<strong>in</strong>gs give direction for policy <strong>in</strong> at least two respects.First, there is a need for the government to attract more good rms <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas<strong>in</strong> which <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> is needed or worthy <strong>experience</strong> can be obta<strong>in</strong>ed. <strong>The</strong>realready exist few examples <strong>of</strong> foreign or <strong>in</strong>ternational rms, which settled <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong>areas and enforced some development <strong>in</strong> the areas around the factory. With thesettl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> a Volks<strong>wage</strong>n plant near Puebla <strong>in</strong> the 1960s, a previously poor <strong>rural</strong>area was turned <strong>in</strong>to a ourish<strong>in</strong>g city by improv<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>frastructure and provid<strong>in</strong>gjobs for skilled and unskilled <strong>work</strong>ers. Suppliers settled <strong>in</strong> a nearby bus<strong>in</strong>ess park,oer<strong>in</strong>g more and diverse employment possibilities. Furthermore, the presence <strong>of</strong>large <strong>in</strong>ter- or mult<strong>in</strong>ational rms from developed countries helps to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> or atleast improve the health and safety standards, the adherence <strong>of</strong> human and labourrights and a relatively high <strong>wage</strong> level. Of course, there are also counter examples <strong>in</strong>some countries, where the presence <strong>of</strong> foreign rms does not <strong>in</strong>crease the standard<strong>of</strong> liv<strong>in</strong>g and the freedoms for the employed <strong>work</strong>force. However, there is supposedlya tendency towards improvement <strong>of</strong> regional labour markets through the settlement<strong>of</strong> particular large rms with an <strong>in</strong>ternational background. Hand <strong>in</strong> hand with theemployment <strong>in</strong> a large rm goes the <strong>in</strong>creased possibility to be registered with theIMSS. <strong>The</strong> descriptive statistics show that the average number <strong>of</strong> employees <strong>in</strong> arm that employs an <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>er is 50, while a formal <strong>work</strong>er has on average119 co-<strong>work</strong>ers. However, the attraction <strong>of</strong> large rm with <strong>in</strong>ternational backgroundis not enough as a mean to <strong>in</strong>crease formal employment. Policies needs to addressthe <strong>in</strong>centives to <strong>work</strong> formally, for example by chang<strong>in</strong>g the current social <strong>in</strong>suranceschemes which impose perverse <strong>in</strong>centives for registration with the IMSS (Levy 2008).6 ConclusionThis study <strong>in</strong>vestigates the dierences <strong>in</strong> <strong>wage</strong>s between <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers <strong>in</strong>the <strong>in</strong>formal and formal sectors <strong>of</strong> Mexico's labour market. Us<strong>in</strong>g the novel, representativeMexican Family Life Survey (MxFLS) is has been shown that a large <strong>urban</strong><strong>wage</strong> premium exists <strong>in</strong> Mexico and that returns to <strong>experience</strong> are small <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areascompared to <strong>urban</strong> areas. Apply<strong>in</strong>g Bl<strong>in</strong>der-Oaxaca Decomposition techniques andcorrect<strong>in</strong>g for selectivity <strong>in</strong>to formal, i.e. registered employment, it has been shownthat <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector the dierences <strong>in</strong> returns to human capital endowments,such as <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong>, education and cognitive ability, expla<strong>in</strong> large parts <strong>of</strong> the<strong>rural</strong>-<strong>urban</strong> <strong>wage</strong> gap. Furthermore, the unexpla<strong>in</strong>ed part is solely based on the difference<strong>in</strong> returns to <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> between <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> <strong>work</strong>ers. Hence, themore <strong>experience</strong> a <strong>work</strong>er has accumulated, the higher is his monetary disadvantage21


when he or she <strong>work</strong>s <strong>in</strong> a <strong>rural</strong> area as compared to an <strong>urban</strong> area. In the formalsector, only dierences <strong>in</strong> education contribute to the explanation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>wage</strong> gapand no dierences <strong>in</strong> coecients can be identied.<strong>The</strong> nd<strong>in</strong>gs suggest that there is a large <strong>in</strong>centive for <strong>rural</strong> residents with atleast some years <strong>of</strong> <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> to migrate from the <strong>rural</strong> <strong>in</strong>to <strong>urban</strong> areas <strong>in</strong>Mexico where they will receive higher rewards for <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong>. If the observed<strong>wage</strong> pattern cont<strong>in</strong>ues to exist, low <strong>rural</strong> returns to <strong>experience</strong> will not only actas a push factor away from <strong>rural</strong> areas and <strong>in</strong>to the big cities but also serve as animpediment for return migration. Moreover, assum<strong>in</strong>g that number <strong>of</strong> <strong>rural</strong>-to-<strong>urban</strong>migrants <strong>in</strong>creases faster than formal jobs emerge, which seems realistic given the low<strong>in</strong>centives to register, either under-employment or <strong>in</strong>formal employment will <strong>in</strong>crease<strong>in</strong> the cities. This will lead to further economic and social problems and cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>glow economic growth.<strong>The</strong> results provide direction for Mexican policy. One way to counteract <strong>rural</strong>to-<strong>urban</strong>migration would be the attraction <strong>of</strong> particular large rms <strong>in</strong> a <strong>rural</strong> area.This improves <strong>in</strong>frastructure, creates jobs and supposedly facilitates to observe theadherence or non-adherence <strong>of</strong> labour rights. Furthermore, large <strong>in</strong>ternational rmstend to pay relatively high <strong>wage</strong>s and are more likely to register their <strong>work</strong>ers withthe IMSS, which <strong>in</strong> turn can reduce poverty and welfare dependency. In such rms,e.g. Volks<strong>wage</strong>n <strong>in</strong> Puebla, <strong>work</strong>ers can accumulate <strong>work</strong> <strong>experience</strong> and becomemore productive for which they will then get accord<strong>in</strong>gly paid. <strong>The</strong> settlement <strong>of</strong>such large rms and the related development could also serve as a pull factor forreturn migration to previously <strong>rural</strong> areas and also generate the <strong>in</strong>centive for the<strong>rural</strong> population to stay.22


ReferencesArias, Javier, Oliver Azuara, Pedro Bernal, James J. Heckman, and CajemeVillarreal, Policies to Promote Growth and Economic Eciency <strong>in</strong> Mexico,IZA Discussion Papers 4740, Institute for the Study <strong>of</strong> Labor (IZA) 2010.Badaoui, Eliane, Eric Strobl, and Frank Walsh, Is <strong>The</strong>re An Informal EmploymentWage Penalty? Evidence from South Africa, Technical Report, IZADiscussion Paper No. 3151 2007.Barga<strong>in</strong>, Oliver and Prudence Kwenda, <strong>The</strong> Informal Sector Wage Gap: NewEvidence Us<strong>in</strong>g Quantile Estimations on Panel Data, Technical Report, IZADiscussion Paper No. 4286 2009.and , Is Informality Bad? Evidence from Brazil, Mexico and SouthAfrica, Technical Report, IZA Discussion Paper No. 4711 2010.Becker, Gary S., Human Capital: A <strong>The</strong>oretical and Empirical Analysis, withSpecial Reference to Education, Chicago, University <strong>of</strong> Chicago Press, 1964.Bl<strong>in</strong>der, Alan, Wage Discrim<strong>in</strong>ation: Reduced Form and Structural Estimates,Journal <strong>of</strong> Human Resources, 1973, 7(4), 43655.Bosch, Mariano and William F. Maloney, Cyclical Movements <strong>in</strong> Unemploymentand Informality <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries, Technical Report, Policy ResearchWork<strong>in</strong>g Paper 4648, <strong>The</strong> World Bank 2008.and William Maloney, Gross Worker Flows <strong>in</strong> the Presence <strong>of</strong> InformalLabor Markets: Evidence from Mexico, 1987-2002, Technical Report, IZA DiscussionPaper No. 2864 2007.Card, David, Chapter 30 <strong>The</strong> causal eect <strong>of</strong> education on earn<strong>in</strong>gs, <strong>in</strong> Orley C.Ashenfelter and David Card, eds., Orley C. Ashenfelter and David Card, eds.,Vol. 3, Part 1 <strong>of</strong> Handbook <strong>of</strong> Labor Economics, Elsevier, 1999, pp. 1801 1863.Fields, Gary S., Rural-<strong>urban</strong> migration, <strong>urban</strong> unemployment and underemployment,and job-search activity <strong>in</strong> LDCs, Journal <strong>of</strong> Development Economics,1975, 2 (2), 165 187.Glaeser, Edward L. and David C. Maré, Cities and Skills, Journal <strong>of</strong> LaborEconomics, 2001, 19 (2), pp. 316342.23


Gong, Xiaodong and Arthur van Soest, Wage dierentials and mobility <strong>in</strong> the<strong>urban</strong> labour market: a panel data analysis for Mexico, Labour Economics,2002, 9 (4), 513 529.Gould, Eric D., Cities, Workers, and Wages: A Structural Analysis <strong>of</strong> the UrbanWage Premium, Review <strong>of</strong> Economic Studies, 2007, 74 (2), 477506.Hamilton, Barton H., Does Entrepreneurship Pay? An Empirical Analysis <strong>of</strong> theReturns <strong>of</strong> Self-Employment, <strong>The</strong> Journal <strong>of</strong> Political Economy, 2000, 108 (3),pp. 604631.Hanson, Gordon H., Why Isn't Mexico Rich?, NBER Work<strong>in</strong>g Papers 16470,National Bureau <strong>of</strong> Economic Research, Inc October 2010.Harris, John R. and Michael P. Todaro, <strong>Migration</strong>, Unemployment and Development:A Two-Sector Analysis, <strong>The</strong> American Economic Review, 1970, 60(1), pp. 126142.Heckman, James J, Sample Selection Bias as a Specication Error, Econometrica,January 1979, 47 (1), 15361.Hsieh, Chang-Tai and Peter J. Klenow, Misallocation and Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g TFP<strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a and India, <strong>The</strong> Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics, 2009, 124 (4), 14031448.Levy, Santiago, Good Intentions, Bad Outcomes: Social Policy, Informality andEconomic Growth <strong>in</strong> Mexico., Brook<strong>in</strong>gs Institution Press, 2008.Lewis, W. Arthur, Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies <strong>of</strong> Labour,<strong>The</strong> Manchester School, 1954, 22, 139191.Lucas, Robert E. Jr., Life Eam<strong>in</strong>gs and Rural-Urban <strong>Migration</strong>, <strong>The</strong> Journal <strong>of</strong>Political Economy, 2004, 112 (1), pp. S29S59.Magnac, Thierry, Segmented or Competitive Labor Markets, Econometrica,1991, 59 (1), pp. 165187.Maloney, William F., Are labor markets <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries dualistic?, PolicyResearch Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper Series 1941, <strong>The</strong> World Bank June 1998., Does Informality Imply Segmentation <strong>in</strong> Urban Labor Markets? Evidencefrom Sectoral Transitions <strong>in</strong> Mexico, World Bank Econ Rev, 1999, 13 (2), 275302., Informality Revisited, World Development, 2004, 32 (7), 1159 1178.24


Marcouiller, Douglas, Veronica Ruiz de Castilla, and ChristopherWoodru, Formal measures <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal-sector <strong>wage</strong> gap <strong>in</strong> Mexico, ElSalvador, and Peru., Economic Development & Cultural Change, 1997, 45 (2),367.Meng, X<strong>in</strong>, <strong>The</strong> Informal Sector and Rural-Urban <strong>Migration</strong> A Ch<strong>in</strong>ese CaseStudy, Asian Economic Journal, 2001, 15(1), 7189.Oaxaca, Ronald, Male-Female Wage Dierentials <strong>in</strong> Urban Labor Markets, InternationalEconomic Review, 1973, 14 (3), pp. 693709.Psacharopoulos, George, Returns to <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> education: A global update,World Development, 1994, 22 (9), 1325 1343.Qu<strong>in</strong>n, Michael A., Relative Deprivation, Wage Dierentials and Mexican <strong>Migration</strong>,Review <strong>of</strong> Development Economics, 02 2006, 10 (1), 135153.Raven, J., J.C. Raven, and J.H. Court, Manual for Raven's Progressive Matricesand Vocabulary Scales. Section 1: General Overview, San Antonio, TX: HarcourtAssessment., 1998, updated 2003.Stark, Oded and J. Edward Taylor, Relative Deprivation and International<strong>Migration</strong>, Demography, 1989, 26 (1), pp. 114.and , <strong>Migration</strong> Incentives, <strong>Migration</strong> Types: <strong>The</strong> Role <strong>of</strong> Relative Deprivation,<strong>The</strong> Economic Journal, 1991, 101 (408), pp. 11631178.Tannuri-Pianto, M and D. Pianto, Informal employment <strong>in</strong> Brazil: a choiceat the top and segmentation at the bottom: a quantile regression approach,Technical Report, Work<strong>in</strong>g paper n 236, Department <strong>of</strong> Economics, University<strong>of</strong> Brasilia 2002.Todaro, Michael P., A Model <strong>of</strong> Labor <strong>Migration</strong> and Urban Unemployment <strong>in</strong>Less Developed Countries, <strong>The</strong> American Economic Review, 1969, 59 (1), pp.138148.World Bank, World Development Indicators (WDI),http://data.worldbank.org/<strong>in</strong>dicator, 2010.25


Appendix26


Table A1: Probit equations Earn<strong>in</strong>g <strong>wage</strong> vs. not earn<strong>in</strong>g <strong>wage</strong>All Rural UrbanProbit MFX Probit MFX Probit MFXEmployeeUrban (d) 0.272*** 0.106*** − − − −(0.033) (0.013)Age 0.126*** 0.049*** 0.112*** 0.040*** 0.138*** 0.055***(0.007) (0.003) (0.012) (0.004) (0.009) (0.004)Age sqrd -0.002*** -0.001*** -0.002*** -0.001*** -0.002*** -0.001***(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)High education (d) 0.372*** 0.147*** 0.277*** 0.103*** 0.413*** 0.163***(0.036) (0.014) (0.068) (0.026) (0.043) (0.017)Raven test 0.165*** 0.065*** 0.265** 0.094** 0.145* 0.058*(0.064) (0.025) (0.103) (0.037) (0.083) (0.033)Log(Other hh earn<strong>in</strong>gs) 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000** 0.000**(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)Log(HH debts) 0.018*** 0.007*** 0.020** 0.007** 0.016*** 0.007***(0.005) (0.002) (0.009) (0.003) (0.006) (0.002)Log(HH non-labour i) -0.005 -0.002 -0.011 -0.004 -0.000 -0.000(0.008) (0.003) (0.014) (0.005) (0.010) (0.004)HH size 0.020*** 0.008*** 0.011* 0.004* 0.028*** 0.011***(0.004) (0.001) (0.006) (0.002) (0.005) (0.002)Nr. <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>fants <strong>in</strong> HH -0.085*** -0.033*** -0.038 -0.013 -0.113*** -0.045***(0.025) (0.010) (0.042) (0.015) (0.032) (0.013)Nr. <strong>of</strong> elderly <strong>in</strong> HH 0.036** 0.014** 0.036 0.013 0.039* 0.016*(0.017) (0.007) (0.026) (0.009) (0.023) (0.009)Indigenous (d) -0.068 -0.026 -0.014 -0.005 -0.126 -0.050(0.051) (0.020) (0.073) (0.026) (0.079) (0.031)Female (d) -1.458*** -0.534*** -1.688*** -0.588*** -1.300*** -0.479***(0.034) (0.010) (0.054) (0.016) (0.044) (0.014)Married (d) -0.394*** -0.154*** -0.396*** -0.141*** -0.397*** -0.157***(0.033) (0.013) (0.055) (0.019) (0.042) (0.017)HH head (d) 0.798*** 0.310*** 0.834*** 0.313*** 0.815*** 0.310***(0.045) (0.016) (0.073) (0.027) (0.058) (0.020)Farm (d) -0.152*** -0.059*** -0.065 -0.023 -0.160* -0.064*(0.046) (0.018) (0.060) (0.021) (0.083) (0.033)Constant -1.807*** − -1.318*** − -1.916*** −(0.151) (0.255) (0.192)State dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesN 10880 10880 4495 4495 6385 6385Pseudo R 2 0.336 0.336 0.385 0.385 0.304 0.304χ 2 5022 5022 2279 2279 2687 2687p 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Note: Standard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses. ∗ , ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ denote signicance level <strong>of</strong> 1%, 5% and 10% respcetively.(d) <strong>in</strong>dicates a descrete change <strong>of</strong> a dummy variable from 0 to 1. <strong>The</strong> dependent variable is employee = 1 if the<strong>in</strong>dividual is a salaried <strong>work</strong>er, and zero otherwise, i.e. the coecients represent the dierence to non <strong>wage</strong> earnersand not <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividuals. 15 state dummies <strong>in</strong>cluded.27


Table A2: Probit equations Formal vs. <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>wage</strong> earnersAll Rural UrbanProbit MFX Probit MFX Probit MFXFormalUrban (d) 0.374*** 0.126*** − − − −(0.047) (0.015)Age 0.068*** 0.024*** 0.043** 0.011** 0.081*** 0.031***(0.011) (0.004) (0.020) (0.005) (0.014) (0.005)Age sqrd -0.001*** -0.000*** -0.001** -0.000** -0.001*** -0.000***(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)High education (d) 0.446*** 0.161*** 0.796*** 0.254*** 0.343*** 0.131***(0.045) (0.017) (0.096) (0.034) (0.052) (0.020)Raven test 0.202** 0.071** -0.020 -0.005 0.319*** 0.121***(0.090) (0.031) (0.165) (0.044) (0.110) (0.041)Log(Other hh earn<strong>in</strong>gs) 0.000 0.000 0.000** 0.000** 0.000 0.000(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)Log(HH debts) 0.012* 0.004* 0.007 0.002 0.011 0.004(0.006) (0.002) (0.014) (0.004) (0.007) (0.003)Log(HH non-labour i) 0.011 0.004 0.020 0.005 0.010 0.004(0.011) (0.004) (0.023) (0.006) (0.013) (0.005)HH size -0.013** -0.005** -0.028*** -0.007*** -0.009 -0.003(0.005) (0.002) (0.010) (0.003) (0.007) (0.002)Nr. <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>fants <strong>in</strong> HH -0.004 -0.002 0.086 0.023 -0.039 -0.015(0.035) (0.012) (0.066) (0.017) (0.043) (0.016)Nr. <strong>of</strong> elderly <strong>in</strong> HH 0.026 0.009 0.043 0.011 0.021 0.008(0.024) (0.008) (0.044) (0.012) (0.030) (0.011)Indigenous (d) -0.012 -0.004 0.117 0.032 -0.053 -0.020(0.075) (0.026) (0.118) (0.033) (0.103) (0.038)Female (d) 0.073 0.026 0.139 0.038 0.039 0.015(0.049) (0.017) (0.095) (0.027) (0.058) (0.022)Married (d) 0.124*** 0.043*** 0.190** 0.051** 0.111** 0.042**(0.047) (0.017) (0.089) (0.024) (0.056) (0.021)HH head (d) 0.050 0.018 0.045 0.012 0.066 0.025(0.060) (0.021) (0.118) (0.031) (0.071) (0.027)Farm (d) -0.081 -0.028 0.077 0.021 -0.257** -0.093**(0.074) (0.025) (0.101) (0.028) (0.122) (0.042)Constant -2.108*** − -1.678*** − -1.945*** −(0.222) (0.407) (0.268)State dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesN 4813 4813 1660 1660 3153 3153Pseudo R 2 0.113 0.113 0.129 0.129 0.090 0.090χ 2 685 685 222 222 379 379p 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Note: Standard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses. ∗ , ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ denote signicance level <strong>of</strong> 1%, 5% and 10% respcetively.(d) <strong>in</strong>dicates a descrete change <strong>of</strong> a dummy variable from 0 to 1. <strong>The</strong> dependent variable is formal = 1 if the<strong>in</strong>dividual is <strong>work</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the formal sector, and zero otherwise, i.e. the coecients represent the dierence to<strong>in</strong>formal sector <strong>work</strong>ers. 15 state dummies <strong>in</strong>cluded.28


Table A3: Wage equations for all, <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>work</strong>ersAll Rural UrbanOLS Heck OLS Heck OLS Heck OLS HeckUrban 0.164 ∗∗∗ 0.170 ∗∗∗ 0.022 0.033 − − − −(0.028) (0.028) (0.088) (0.088)Exp*Urban − − 0.010 ∗ 0.010 ∗ − − − −(0.006) (0.006)Exp sq.*Urban − − -0.013 -0.012 − − − −(0.011) (0.011)High edu.*Urban − − 0.034 0.033 − − − −(0.068) (0.067)Raven*Urban − − 0.013 0.015 − − − −(0.103) (0.102)Experience 0.014 ∗∗∗ 0.018 ∗∗∗ 0.007 0.011 ∗∗ 0.003 0.004 0.017 ∗∗∗ 0.021 ∗∗∗(0.003) (0.004) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.006) (0.004) (0.005)Experience sq/100 -0.027 ∗∗∗ -0.037 ∗∗∗ -0.019 ∗∗ -0.027 ∗∗∗ -0.013 -0.016 -0.029 ∗∗∗ -0.041 ∗∗∗(0.006) (0.008) (0.008) (0.010) (0.009) (0.013) (0.008) (0.011)High education 0.206 ∗∗∗ 0.202 ∗∗∗ 0.189 ∗∗∗ 0.185 ∗∗∗ 0.179 ∗∗∗ 0.173 ∗∗∗ 0.208 ∗∗∗ 0.215 ∗∗∗(0.034) (0.035) (0.059) (0.059) (0.064) (0.066) (0.041) (0.042)Raven test 0.113 ∗∗ 0.113 ∗∗ 0.104 0.104 0.068 0.077 0.101 0.073(0.052) (0.053) (0.078) (0.078) (0.080) (0.084) (0.068) (0.074)HH size -0.001 0.003 -0.001 0.002 0.005 0.006 -0.004 0.002(0.003) (0.004) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.003) (0.006)Indigenous -0.065 ∗ -0.076 ∗ -0.063 -0.072 ∗ -0.063 -0.066 -0.046 -0.049(0.039) (0.041) (0.039) (0.040) (0.054) (0.054) (0.062) (0.064)Female -0.144 ∗∗∗ -0.374 ∗∗ -0.146 ∗∗∗ -0.331 ∗∗ -0.155 ∗∗∗ -0.227 -0.143 ∗∗∗ -0.409 ∗∗(0.034) (0.145) (0.034) (0.146) (0.059) (0.242) (0.042) (0.191)HH head 0.002 0.081 0.003 0.066 0.079 0.102 -0.017 0.087(0.032) (0.058) (0.032) (0.058) (0.051) (0.092) (0.042) (0.085)Married 0.102 ∗∗∗ 0.025 0.102 ∗∗∗ 0.040 0.042 0.024 0.124 ∗∗∗ 0.010(0.027) (0.055) (0.027) (0.055) (0.044) (0.074) (0.035) (0.087)Constant 2.854 ∗∗∗ 2.563 ∗∗∗ 2.948 ∗∗∗ 2.710 ∗∗∗ 3.067 ∗∗∗ 3.001 ∗∗∗ 2.989 ∗∗∗ 2.559 ∗∗∗(0.112) (0.211) (0.122) (0.220) (0.183) (0.280) (0.155) (0.337)λ f/<strong>in</strong>f − 0.303 − 0.244 − 0.074 − 0.432(0.186) (0.187) (0.242) (0.302)State dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesIndustry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesOccup. dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesN 3249 10880 3249 10880 1306 4495 1943 6385¯R 2 0.226 − 0.226 − 0.175 − 0.229 −χ 2 − 994 − 1013 − 349 − 615p 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Note: Standard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses. ∗ , ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ denote signicance level <strong>of</strong> 1%, 5% and 10% respcetively.OLS: Ord<strong>in</strong>ary Least Squares, Heck: Heckman Selection 2nd step. λ is the nonselection hazard variable generatedfrom the probit model. 15 state dummies, 23 <strong>in</strong>dustry dummies and 18 occupation dummies <strong>in</strong>cluded.29


Table A4: Wage equations for all, <strong>rural</strong> and <strong>urban</strong> formal <strong>work</strong>ersAll Rural UrbanOLS Heck OLS Heck OLS Heck OLS HeckUrban 0.176 ∗∗∗ 0.180 ∗∗∗ -0.006 -0.017 − − − −(0.038) (0.057) (0.144) (0.152)Exp*Urban − − 0.005 0.005 − − − −(0.009) (0.009)Exp sq.*Urban − − 0.000 0.000 − − − −(0.018) (0.018)High edu.*Urban − − 0.021 0.022 − − − −(0.080) (0.079)Raven*Urban − − 0.149 0.150 − − − −(0.160) (0.156)Experience 0.014 ∗∗∗ 0.014 ∗∗ 0.010 0.009 0.003 -0.008 0.015 ∗∗∗ 0.015 ∗∗(0.004) (0.006) (0.008) (0.009) (0.010) (0.012) (0.005) (0.007)Experience sq/100 -0.026 ∗∗∗ -0.027 ∗∗ -0.025 -0.023 -0.014 0.008 -0.025 ∗∗ -0.026 ∗(0.009) (0.012) (0.016) (0.018) (0.017) (0.022) (0.010) (0.015)High education 0.250 ∗∗∗ 0.256 ∗∗∗ 0.234 ∗∗∗ 0.222 ∗∗ 0.157 -0.149 0.259 ∗∗∗ 0.266 ∗∗∗(0.039) (0.071) (0.076) (0.100) (0.105) (0.226) (0.042) (0.070)Raven test 0.097 0.099 -0.020 -0.025 -0.072 -0.099 0.131 ∗ 0.134(0.068) (0.070) (0.139) (0.138) (0.149) (0.145) (0.078) (0.083)HH size -0.004 -0.004 -0.004 -0.004 0.006 0.007 -0.007 -0.007(0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.009) (0.008) (0.004) (0.004)Indigenous 0.010 0.009 0.010 0.011 -0.048 -0.099 0.049 0.048(0.059) (0.058) (0.059) (0.058) (0.113) (0.113) (0.074) (0.073)Female -0.003 -0.008 -0.002 0.009 0.082 0.334 ∗ -0.016 -0.023(0.038) (0.069) (0.039) (0.069) (0.085) (0.185) (0.044) (0.069)HH head 0.060 0.063 0.062 0.055 0.127 0.016 0.043 0.048(0.042) (0.056) (0.042) (0.057) (0.093) (0.117) (0.048) (0.064)Married 0.044 0.042 0.046 0.049 -0.006 0.038 0.054 0.052(0.033) (0.037) (0.033) (0.037) (0.080) (0.082) (0.037) (0.041)Constant 3.013 ∗∗∗ 2.988 ∗∗∗ 3.173 ∗∗∗ 3.225 ∗∗∗ 2.411 ∗∗∗ 3.267 ∗∗∗ 3.467 ∗∗∗ 3.439 ∗∗∗(0.148) (0.302) (0.188) (0.337) (0.289) (0.623) (0.152) (0.286)λ f/<strong>in</strong>f − 0.012 − -0.025 − -0.449 − 0.016(0.133) (0.135) (0.296) (0.142)State dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesIndustry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesOccup. dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesN 1564 10880 1564 10880 354 4495 1210 6385¯R 2 0.375 − 0.375 − 0.350 − 0.380 −− χ 2 − 864 − 869 − 257 − 722p 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Note: Standard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses. ∗ , ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ denote signicance level <strong>of</strong> 1%, 5% and 10% respcetively.OLS: Ord<strong>in</strong>ary Least Squares, Heck: Heckman Selection 2nd step. λ is the nonselection hazard variable generatedfrom the probit model. 15 state dummies, 23 <strong>in</strong>dustry dummies and 18 occupation dummies <strong>in</strong>cluded.30


Table A5: Decomposition overall resultsALL Informal FormalOLS Heck OLS Heck OLS HeckUrban 2.957*** 2.957*** 2.848*** 2.848*** 3.133*** 3.133***(0.013) (0.013) (0.017) (0.017) (0.020) (0.020)Rural 2.625*** 2.625*** 2.559*** 2.559*** 2.869*** 2.869***(0.018) (0.018) (0.020) (0.020) (0.037) (0.037)Dierence 0.333*** 0.333*** 0.289*** 0.289*** 0.264*** 0.264***(0.022) (0.022) (0.026) (0.026) (0.042) (0.042)Expla<strong>in</strong>ed 0.165*** 0.155*** 0.125*** 0.123*** 0.089*** 0.090***(0.016) (0.020) (0.019) (0.019) (0.030) (0.030)Unexpla<strong>in</strong>ed 0.168*** 0.178*** 0.164*** 0.166*** 0.175*** 0.174***(0.022) (0.025) (0.027) (0.028) (0.037) (0.038)N 4183 3249 1564Note: Standard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses. ∗ , ∗∗ and ∗∗∗ denote signicance level <strong>of</strong> 1%, 5% and 10% respcetively. OLS:Ord<strong>in</strong>ary Least Squares, Heck: Heckman Selection two-step. <strong>The</strong> decomposition is formulated from the viewpo<strong>in</strong>t<strong>of</strong> the <strong>rural</strong> population. For the underly<strong>in</strong>g regressions see <strong>wage</strong> regression tables.31

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!