13.07.2015 Views

University-related science parks - 'seedbeds' or 'enclaves' of ...

University-related science parks - 'seedbeds' or 'enclaves' of ...

University-related science parks - 'seedbeds' or 'enclaves' of ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

0. Felsensteina supp<strong>or</strong>tive environment f<strong>or</strong> the development <strong>of</strong>innovation, creativity and entrepreneurship.The above description stresses the seedbed role<strong>of</strong> the <strong>science</strong> park in a behavioural sense.However, another set <strong>of</strong> expectations <strong>of</strong> <strong>science</strong><strong>parks</strong> relates to their function in a regionaleconomic development sense. Science <strong>parks</strong> areinvariably associated with m<strong>or</strong>e than just a rolein promoting innovation and entrepreneurialism,and a successful <strong>science</strong> park is viewed as m<strong>or</strong>ethan an innovation-generating environment. It is<strong>of</strong>ten - wishfully - ascribed with the properties<strong>of</strong> a growth sect<strong>or</strong> leading the area under questioninto a spiral <strong>of</strong> propulsive expansion [4, 51. Thefew success st<strong>or</strong>ies notwithstanding, the reality israther m<strong>or</strong>e mundane. The <strong>science</strong> park as acatalyst in urban and regional growth is not a welltroddenpath and, despite public policy rhet<strong>or</strong>ic tothe contrary, few examples exist <strong>of</strong> <strong>science</strong> parkledlocal economic development [6].The common ground between the behaviouraland spatial conceptions <strong>of</strong> the seedbed lies in thenotion <strong>of</strong> the seedbed as creating an environment.This environment, while occupying dimensions ingeometric space, is not exclusively spatial. Itrepresents a ‘milieu’ in both the functional andbehavioural sense, as well as the geographic.Amongst the principal fact<strong>or</strong>s <strong>of</strong> production in<strong>science</strong> park development are inf<strong>or</strong>mation andknow-how which are inherently unconstrained byspatial boundaries. The <strong>science</strong> park as a seedbedf<strong>or</strong> innovation is m<strong>or</strong>e than just a physical concentration<strong>of</strong> units <strong>of</strong> production benefiting from thelinkages and economies <strong>of</strong> scale and scope thatagglomeration aff<strong>or</strong>ds. As will be seen below,these advantages are not <strong>of</strong>ten realized and theinnovation process does not seem to be contingenton them.There must theref<strong>or</strong>e be a further aspect <strong>of</strong> theseedbed environment that is <strong>related</strong> to behaviouralfact<strong>or</strong>s and is also imp<strong>or</strong>tant in understanding therelationship between <strong>science</strong> park location andinnovation. This relates to the netw<strong>or</strong>k environment<strong>of</strong> the firm that comprises the inf<strong>or</strong>maland non-institutionalized flows <strong>of</strong> inf<strong>or</strong>mation,knowledge and collab<strong>or</strong>ation based on contacts,w<strong>or</strong>k experience, education and so on. Thesefact<strong>or</strong>s, while difficult to quantify, add a furtherdimension to the seedbed function <strong>of</strong> the <strong>science</strong>park and also transcend its narrow spatial confines.This paper examines the relationship betweeninnovation and <strong>science</strong> park location and, in sodoing, highlights these different conceptions <strong>of</strong> theseedbed function. An empirical analysis, based onevidence from <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> in Israel, is presented.While no attempt is made to determine thedirection <strong>of</strong> causality between level <strong>of</strong> innovationand location on a <strong>science</strong> park (does <strong>science</strong> parklocation make f<strong>or</strong> m<strong>or</strong>e innovative firms, <strong>or</strong> dothe m<strong>or</strong>e innovative tend to cluster in <strong>science</strong><strong>parks</strong>?), we are interested in unravelling some <strong>of</strong>the relationships between innovation, location andthe behavioural characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>science</strong> parkcompany entrepreneurs and managers. This willshed light on the seedbed functions <strong>of</strong> the <strong>science</strong>park, both behavioural and spatial.M<strong>or</strong>e specifically, the paper proceeds in thefollowing manner. The main tenets <strong>of</strong> the seedbedenvironment, from both a behavioural and a spatialperspective, are highlighted in the next section,and the empirical evidence f<strong>or</strong> <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> asseedbeds is presented. This is followed by ash<strong>or</strong>t description <strong>of</strong> the context within which theempirical w<strong>or</strong>k is set, and a f<strong>or</strong>mulation <strong>of</strong> themain hypotheses. Data limitations and issues <strong>of</strong>method are then discussed and this leads on tothe empirical findings. On the basis <strong>of</strong> a survey<strong>of</strong> over 160 Israeli high-technology firms and threemaj<strong>or</strong> university-<strong>related</strong> <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>, some <strong>of</strong> therelationships between behavioural characteristics,<strong>science</strong> park location and innovation level areestimated. The significance <strong>of</strong> these findings withrespect to the role <strong>of</strong> <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> in the innovationprocess, and their policy implications, are presentedin the concluding section.2. The seedbed environmentIn defining the conditions that give rise to theseedbed environment, a distinction needs to bedrawn between the spatial and the behavioural94 Technovation Vol. 14 No. 2


Science <strong>parks</strong> - seedbeds <strong>or</strong> enclaves <strong>of</strong> innovation?approaches. From a spatial perspective, theexogenous fact<strong>or</strong>s nurturing and promoting innovationat a given location are integral components<strong>of</strong> the seedbed environment. Much eff<strong>or</strong>t has beenexpended in identifying those areas that have‘good’ incubat<strong>or</strong> conditions based on city size,level <strong>of</strong> urbanization, institutional structures andcommunity characteristics [7, 81. While the evidenceon the impact <strong>of</strong> these influences oninnovation is mixed, it does seem to suggest thaturban areas are not particularly imp<strong>or</strong>tant marketsf<strong>or</strong> the development <strong>of</strong> innovative activity. In fact,a study <strong>of</strong> the incubat<strong>or</strong> function <strong>of</strong> the Raandstadcities in Holland has shown these locations to beunder-represented in terms <strong>of</strong> innovative activity[9]. The spatial seedbed hypothesis <strong>of</strong> an indigenousregional impact supp<strong>or</strong>ting innovation could theref<strong>or</strong>enot be supp<strong>or</strong>ted and the study suggestslooking at intra-firm characteristics f<strong>or</strong> furtherexplanation.While this spatial approach relates to the determinants<strong>of</strong> innovative activity, other approacheshave looked, from this same perspective, at thedeterminants <strong>of</strong> the incidence <strong>of</strong> industrial and<strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>. The presence <strong>of</strong> industrial <strong>parks</strong> ingeneral has been <strong>related</strong> to city (<strong>or</strong> community)size and age, population densities and populationgrowth rates [lo]. Looking m<strong>or</strong>e specifically at<strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>, Luger and Goldstein [ll] havedemonstrated the imp<strong>or</strong>tance <strong>of</strong> size <strong>of</strong> metropolitanarea, linkage to a local university and level <strong>of</strong>service <strong>of</strong>fered, in explaining <strong>science</strong> park successas measured by employment generation. Conversely,<strong>parks</strong> located in small areas and withoutuniversity connections are the most likely to fail.This identification <strong>of</strong> seedbed characteristics hasnot been without its critics. As an approach tounderstanding location tendencies it has beentermed ‘analytically sterile’ [12 (p. 219)] and it isclaimed that innovative places cannot be ‘read-<strong>of</strong>fon the basis <strong>of</strong> the ‘right’ exogenously determinedcharacteristics. Furtherm<strong>or</strong>e, such an approach, itis argued, misses the subtle role played by industrial<strong>or</strong>ganizations and overlooks the social divisions <strong>of</strong>labour that have allowed the seedbed to emerge.In essence, a behavioural component <strong>of</strong> seedbedf<strong>or</strong>mation is missing. This would include the role<strong>of</strong> exogenous <strong>or</strong>ganizations <strong>or</strong> institutions such asuniversities, the role <strong>of</strong> other firms in promoting<strong>or</strong> discouraging spin-<strong>of</strong>fs, previous w<strong>or</strong>k and educationalbackground <strong>of</strong> entrepreneurs, and so on.From a behavioural perspective, the seedbedenvironment is composed <strong>of</strong> a knowledge infrastructure(such as a university <strong>or</strong> research institute)that creates positive externalities that becomepublic goods. These institutions can also includelocal chambers <strong>of</strong> commerce, banks, venture capitalcompanies and so on. These are all milieu-creating<strong>or</strong>ganizations [13] in that, when they occur withina given area, they create an inf<strong>or</strong>mation- andtransaction-intensive complex that not only provideseconomies in scale and scope and cost savingsin transactions but also reduces risk [14].Other firms also have an imp<strong>or</strong>tant role to playin fashioning the behavioural environment. Theyare sources <strong>of</strong> knowledge and externalities no lessthan the institutions mentioned above. As Acs andAudretsch [15] point out, other firms (competit<strong>or</strong>s,collab<strong>or</strong>at<strong>or</strong>s) are reposit<strong>or</strong>ies <strong>of</strong> know-how andw<strong>or</strong>k experience. Some <strong>of</strong> this is accessed throughf<strong>or</strong>mal sources such as contracts and licensingagreements while some is generated through meetings,trade fairs, inf<strong>or</strong>mal contacts and intermediariessuch as suppliers and consultants. Where allthis occurs in a given environment such as a<strong>science</strong> park, the spatial and behavioural fact<strong>or</strong>sinterchange. However, as Birley [16] has pointedout, in a local environment one <strong>of</strong> the maininf<strong>or</strong>mational sh<strong>or</strong>tcomings is the lack <strong>of</strong> kncwledgeas to what inf<strong>or</strong>mation is in fact available.This would seem to suggest, f<strong>or</strong> example, thatfirms choosing to locate on a <strong>science</strong> park maynot necessarily be exercising this choice because<strong>of</strong> its perceived seedbed function. They <strong>of</strong>ten setupwithout a proper screening process <strong>of</strong> theenvironment, and their location choice may bepart <strong>of</strong> a ‘social signalling’ process [17]. Theseedbed properties <strong>of</strong> the environment (access toinf<strong>or</strong>mation, netw<strong>or</strong>ks etc.) are then probably onlyrealized at a later stage. This could also seem tosuggest that initially the innovative capacities <strong>of</strong> anew firm in an environment such as a <strong>science</strong> parkTechnovation Vol. 14 No. 2 95


D. Felsensteinare not fully exploited. This is because innovationis <strong>related</strong> to the seedbed environment, which ishypothesized to be an unknown quantity at theearly stages <strong>of</strong> firm development.3. Science <strong>parks</strong> as seedbedsEvidence exists suggesting that, in spatial termsat least, universities do have a seedbed effect ontheir local economies. A series <strong>of</strong> aggregateanalyses on the effects <strong>of</strong> universities on metropolitanareas <strong>or</strong> regions in the United States hasshown this effect to be wide ranging. ThusJaffe [18] has found a relationship between firminnovation rates (measured by patents) and thelevel <strong>of</strong> local university research. This suggests theexistence <strong>of</strong> technological ‘spillovers’ that benefitfirms in proximity to universities. Further evidence<strong>of</strong> this aggregate spillover effect comes from Bania,Eberts and Fogarty [19], who attribute higherlevels <strong>of</strong> .new firm f<strong>or</strong>mation rates to those placeswith concentrations <strong>of</strong> highly skilled universitylabour, and from Beeson and Montgomery [20],who suggest that this spillover effect can alsoaffect occupational composition. They show thatthe level <strong>of</strong> R&D funding at a local universityincreases the odds <strong>of</strong> being employed locally as ascientist <strong>or</strong> engineer <strong>or</strong> being employed in a localhigh-technology industry. This seedbed functionalso serves to entrench future rounds <strong>of</strong> growthas evidenced by universities’ ability to attractscientific infrastructure. F<strong>or</strong> metropolitan areas, ithas been shown that industrial R&D labs tend toconcentrate in those areas where levels <strong>of</strong> universityresearch are highest [21]. This relationship hasalso been found on the basis <strong>of</strong> case-study analysis[22].1It should be noted, however, that evidence fromoutside the US is m<strong>or</strong>e equivocal. In the case <strong>of</strong>Japan, f<strong>or</strong> example, Eto and Fujita [28] reject thehypothesis that universities are instrumental ingenerating high-tech firm growth. They find strongevidence <strong>of</strong> the self-entrenching effects <strong>of</strong> hightechgrowth and that scientific-industrial agglomerationswill tend to reproduce themselves. This can<strong>of</strong>ten take place in proximity to leading universities,although they find no real causality in this process.Similarly, Fl<strong>or</strong>ax and Folmer [29] show that, inthe case <strong>of</strong> Holland, the diffusion <strong>of</strong> knowledgeis not necessarily a function <strong>of</strong> spatial clusteringaround universities. This seems to imply littlespillover effect, in small countries at least.Overall, however, the claims f<strong>or</strong> a significantuniversity seeding effect on the local economy,with respect to innovation level, new firm startuprates, occupational composition and so on,seem to be well founded. Evidence attributing asimilar role to <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>, however, is ratherm<strong>or</strong>e mixed. In terms <strong>of</strong> new firm f<strong>or</strong>mation,Massey et al. [6] find mixed evidence f<strong>or</strong> British<strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>. On the one hand, new start-upsf<strong>or</strong>m a clear min<strong>or</strong>ity (less than 30%) <strong>of</strong> firms on<strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> and in much celebrated seedbeds,such as Cambridge, this figure is less than 10%.On the other hand, new start-ups on <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>have a much lower m<strong>or</strong>tality rate than that <strong>of</strong> newfirms in general (less than 2.5% a year). Thiscould however reflect a screening process f<strong>or</strong><strong>science</strong> park entry that selects only firms withgood survival chances. In the US, case studyevidence shows great variation. On the ResearchTriangle Park, f<strong>or</strong> example, over 70% <strong>of</strong> firms arepart <strong>of</strong> multi-plant <strong>or</strong>ganizations whose existencecannot be attributed to the park. The <strong>University</strong><strong>of</strong> Utah Research Park, on the other hand, haslocal, single-plant <strong>or</strong>ganizations comprising m<strong>or</strong>ethan half the park population [ll].Science park-based spin-<strong>of</strong>fs that trace their rootsto the university are another seedbed characteristic.While much attention traditionally has beenfocused on existing firms spawning new firms [30],spin-<strong>of</strong>fs emanating from a university environmenthave received much less attention [31]. Nevertheless,accounts <strong>of</strong> locally based company genealogiesnearly always put the local university <strong>or</strong> <strong>science</strong>park at the apex <strong>of</strong> any ‘family tree’ account <strong>of</strong>seedbed growth.Survey evidence from firms located on Dutchand Belgian <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> indicates that only 37%<strong>of</strong> firms in the f<strong>or</strong>mer and 16% in the latterattribute their <strong>or</strong>igins to universities [32]. In the96 Technovation Vol. 14 No. 2


Science <strong>parks</strong> - seedbeds <strong>or</strong> enclaves <strong>of</strong> innovation?US, again the variation across individual <strong>parks</strong> isvery great. Thus, Luger and Goldstein [II] havefound that over 120 spin-<strong>of</strong>f companies in thevicinity <strong>of</strong> the Stanf<strong>or</strong>d Research Park haveuniversity antecedents whereas f<strong>or</strong> the ResearchTriangle Park the number <strong>of</strong> university spin-<strong>of</strong>fsis virtually nil. Massey et al. [6] show that, f<strong>or</strong>UK <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>, on aggregate 25% <strong>of</strong> firms mayhave their beginnings in academia although some<strong>of</strong> these are likely to be analytic service units <strong>or</strong>technical troubleshooting operations that, pri<strong>or</strong> tothe establishment <strong>of</strong> the <strong>science</strong> park, were locatedwithin the university. Even at the level <strong>of</strong> theindividual park unit, while a location such as theCambridge Science Park is much heralded as aspin-<strong>of</strong>f incubat<strong>or</strong> and (in 1987) nearly 400 localfirms owed their ultimate <strong>or</strong>igin to the localuniversity in one way <strong>or</strong> another, direct universityinvolvement in their establishment was much m<strong>or</strong>ecircumspect. Segal Quince Wicksteed [33] rep<strong>or</strong>tsthat less than 20% <strong>of</strong> new companies were f<strong>or</strong>medby direct university entrants.If the <strong>science</strong> park functions as an effectiveseedbed, it is assumed that the level <strong>of</strong> R&Dconducted by firms located on <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> isgenerally higher than that <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>f-park firms andthat this reflects the level <strong>of</strong> (close) interactionpresumed to exist between <strong>science</strong> park firms andthe local university. The <strong>science</strong> park is thusperceived as an imp<strong>or</strong>tant conduit in technologytransfer out <strong>of</strong> the university and into the localeconomy.Van Dierdonck et al. [32] present a ratherdifferent picture based on <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> in Belgiumand Holland. They show rather low levels <strong>of</strong>interaction perf<strong>or</strong>mance between park tenants andlocal universities, with the overall level <strong>of</strong> R&Dactivity perf<strong>or</strong>med on the park being lower thanpopularly anticipated. Only 32% <strong>of</strong> Dutch firmsand 57% <strong>of</strong> Belgian firms surveyed rep<strong>or</strong>ted inhouseR&D, and little R&D interaction wasrep<strong>or</strong>ted with either local (<strong>science</strong> park) firms <strong>or</strong>the local university. In fact, f<strong>or</strong> many <strong>science</strong> parkfirms, external research linkages were not locallydefined and were conducted on an internationalscale, pointing to the existence <strong>of</strong> research netw<strong>or</strong>ksunconstrained by national boundaries. Similarly,Massey et al. [6] find <strong>science</strong> park tenant firms inthe UK less ‘leading edge’ than generally imagined.On the inputs side, over 40% <strong>of</strong> employees on<strong>parks</strong> were scientists and engineers2 and R&Dexpenditures in relation to sales were very high.On the outputs side, despite a greater propensityto patent amongst on-park than <strong>of</strong>f-park firms,most firms were found to be engaged in modification<strong>of</strong> existing technologies rather than thedevelopment and production <strong>of</strong> totally new innovations.Complementing this picture is the evidencepointing to the generally low level <strong>of</strong> links between<strong>science</strong> park firms and local universities. Mostaccessing <strong>of</strong> academic resources relates to lowlevelcontacts based on recruiting university graduates,<strong>or</strong> inf<strong>or</strong>mal contacts [6]. Joint research <strong>or</strong>subcontracting relations are much less pr<strong>of</strong>use.F<strong>or</strong> UK <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> only 14% <strong>of</strong> companiesrep<strong>or</strong>ted such links, and a survey <strong>of</strong> two maj<strong>or</strong><strong>parks</strong> in Israel rep<strong>or</strong>ted a similar figure [34]. Firmson US <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> have also indicated thatrecruitment <strong>of</strong> graduates and use <strong>of</strong> universityfacilities f<strong>or</strong>m their main points <strong>of</strong> contact withuniversities. Thus, f<strong>or</strong> both the Research TrianglePark and the <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> Utah Research Park,technology transfer to local firms (both on- and<strong>of</strong>f-park) was low [ll]. F<strong>or</strong> these firms the localuniversity was not a particularly imp<strong>or</strong>tant source<strong>of</strong> R&D inputs <strong>or</strong> innovations. Even f<strong>or</strong> theStanf<strong>or</strong>d Research Park, generally accredited withbeing an archetypal ‘seedbed’, local firms did notrep<strong>or</strong>t a significant seeding effect. Thus, while80% <strong>of</strong> on-park firms rep<strong>or</strong>ted links with Stanf<strong>or</strong>d,over 70% <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>f-park firms said they had noconnection.These observed levels <strong>of</strong> university-<strong>science</strong> parkinteraction have led to suggestions that hightechnologyfirms are m<strong>or</strong>e dependent on linkagesand inf<strong>or</strong>mation flows from other similar firmsthan on interaction with universities [35]. If thisis the case, there should be evidence <strong>of</strong> <strong>science</strong>park firms seeding the local economy throughtheir material input-output patterns. However,examining the external purchase and sales linkagesTechnovation Vol. 14 No. 2


D. Felsensteinthat <strong>science</strong> park firms have with local <strong>of</strong>f-parkfirms, it becomes apparent that in many cases thesestructures are limited. This is hardly surprising inview <strong>of</strong> the increasingly national and internationalmarkets that high-technology firms are serving [36,371. When the local market is also a leadingmarket nationally, <strong>science</strong> park firms are likely toseed the local economy in terms <strong>of</strong> inputs andoutputs. Thus, while firms located on the Stanf<strong>or</strong>dResearch Park have heavy reliance on Calif<strong>or</strong>niaf<strong>or</strong> non-labour inputs, firms in the ResearchTriangle Park have little interaction with eachother <strong>or</strong> with <strong>of</strong>f-park firms [ll]. Limited salesand purchase links with the local economy havealso been rep<strong>or</strong>ted in the case <strong>of</strong> Cambridge, withover 70% <strong>of</strong> local firms rep<strong>or</strong>ting either no linkages<strong>or</strong> interactions <strong>of</strong> min<strong>or</strong> significance [38]. Similarevidence with respect to external material linkagesexists f<strong>or</strong> <strong>science</strong> park complexes in both Canada[39] and Australia [40].The level <strong>of</strong> inter-firm linkage is <strong>of</strong> courseheavily contingent on fact<strong>or</strong>s exogenous to the<strong>science</strong> park, such as firm <strong>or</strong>ganizational structureand market structure. Science <strong>parks</strong> characterizedby branch plants are likely to have less localproducer-supplier relations than <strong>parks</strong> composed<strong>of</strong> independent, single-facility units [41]. Marketstructure, similarly, is likely to dictate the level <strong>of</strong>local linkage. Customized production rather thanmass production is m<strong>or</strong>e likely to have a localseeding effect in terms <strong>of</strong> external linkages andspin-<strong>of</strong>fs [42].It should be noted that, even if local linkagestructures are weak, this does not mean that thetotal impact <strong>of</strong> the <strong>science</strong> park on the localeconomy is negligible. Input-output studies thathave tried to capture the induced effect onlocal incomes, output and employment point toconsiderable impacts attributable to the <strong>science</strong>park. In employment terms, Luger and Goldstein[ll], f<strong>or</strong> example, estimate total employmentimpact (direct and indirect) as ranging from over4000 jobs f<strong>or</strong> Utah to 75000 jobs in the case <strong>of</strong>Stanf<strong>or</strong>d3. While this represents much m<strong>or</strong>e thana seeding effect, it does indicate the growthpotential <strong>of</strong> a process that expands by a fixedmultiple <strong>of</strong> its initial injection.While the behavioural fact<strong>or</strong>s inducing seedbedf<strong>or</strong>mation have been examined in relation toinnovation and the entrepreneurial process ingeneral [l, 161, they have not been studied withrespect to <strong>science</strong> park firms in particular. If the<strong>science</strong> park does function as a seedbed f<strong>or</strong>innovation, then we might expect to find differencesin these behavioural fact<strong>or</strong>s between on- and <strong>of</strong>fparkfirms. However, a case study <strong>of</strong> the CentralFl<strong>or</strong>ida Science Park and its environs could notsupp<strong>or</strong>t this contention. The behavioural milieu,from which chief executive <strong>of</strong>ficers (CEOs) <strong>of</strong>both <strong>science</strong> park and non-<strong>science</strong> park firmsemerged, was very similar with respect to w<strong>or</strong>kexperience, educational background and managementskills [37].4. The setting and hypotheses<strong>University</strong>-<strong>related</strong> <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> in Israel are aresult <strong>of</strong> a government decision taken at theend <strong>of</strong> the 1960s to improve university-industryinteraction through the establishment <strong>of</strong>technological-industrial complexes in proximity tomaj<strong>or</strong> universities. Over the 197Os, four suchcampuses were constructed, associated with theWeizmann Institute <strong>of</strong> Science at Rehovot (a citysouth <strong>of</strong> Tel Aviv but lying within the Tel Avivmetropolitan area), the Technion - Israel Institute<strong>of</strong> Technology - at Haifa, the Hebrew <strong>University</strong><strong>of</strong> Jerusalem and Tel Aviv <strong>University</strong>. Firms fromthree out <strong>of</strong> these four maj<strong>or</strong> <strong>parks</strong> are surveyedhere (the exception being the Technion).These <strong>parks</strong> were constructed with the help <strong>of</strong>liberal government assistance administered underthe Law f<strong>or</strong> the Encouragement <strong>of</strong> Capital Investment, Israel’s principal vehicle f<strong>or</strong> assisting industry[43]. Prospective tenants f<strong>or</strong> the <strong>parks</strong> were to bescreened by the Office <strong>of</strong> the Chief Scientist atthe Ministry <strong>of</strong> Industry and Trade, and the finaldecision on acceptance was to be in the hands <strong>of</strong>the local park auth<strong>or</strong>ities. In practice, a lack <strong>of</strong>clear selection criteria resulted in a m<strong>or</strong>e haphazardentry process [43] and each park eventually createdits own set <strong>of</strong> entry qualifications in line with thegeneral objectives and character <strong>of</strong> the specificpark.98 Technovation Vol. 14 No. 2


Science <strong>parks</strong> - seedbeds <strong>or</strong> enclaves <strong>of</strong> innovation?Site development and park management varyfrom case to case. In all <strong>parks</strong> there is f<strong>or</strong>malassociation with the university although, in practice,academic involvement in management anddevelopment is minimal. Thus, in Rehovot, theuniversity has vested all its auth<strong>or</strong>ity in a privatedevelopment company. In Jerusalem, responsibilityf<strong>or</strong> the park is divided between local government,a recently privatized city development c<strong>or</strong>p<strong>or</strong>ationand the various large tenants in the park whogenerally deal directly with central government.Needless to say, this situation is not withoutproblems [34] and in recent years the universityhas reduced its involvement in the park to aminimum. In Haifa, the city’s economic developmentc<strong>or</strong>p<strong>or</strong>ation has set up a subsidiary tomanage, develop and promote the park; and inTel Aviv, park management is similarly in the hands<strong>of</strong> a joint local auth<strong>or</strong>ity-university subsidiary.The <strong>parks</strong> theref<strong>or</strong>e represent planned environmentsinitiated and <strong>or</strong>iginally promoted by centralgovernment but whose development traject<strong>or</strong>yhas, over time, devolved to local government andits institutions. Only in one <strong>of</strong> the four cases havedevelopment and management been handed overto private interests.Physically, all <strong>parks</strong> have been developed inmaj<strong>or</strong> urban centres but on sites distinct fromexisting industrial areas and generally in proximityto residential neighbourhoods.Turning now to the hypotheses, this paperexamines the contention that, in practice, <strong>science</strong><strong>parks</strong> function m<strong>or</strong>e as enclaves <strong>of</strong> innovationthan as seedbeds. The empirical evidence reviewedabove has served to stress the rather limitedseedbed role that most <strong>parks</strong> play, especially inrespect to linkages with local universities, newfirm f<strong>or</strong>mation, incidence <strong>of</strong> spin-<strong>of</strong>fs and linkageswith the local economy. The perf<strong>or</strong>mance <strong>of</strong> <strong>parks</strong>in all these spheres and their rather constrainedinteraction patterns suggest that <strong>parks</strong> may functionas ‘islands’ <strong>of</strong> innovation (see [6], p. 53) <strong>or</strong> ascollections <strong>of</strong> firms with no real links betweenthem. While we are not proposing that the physicalconfiguration <strong>of</strong> the park has any role to play inits functional sense as a seedbed, we can hypothes-ize that the geographic separation that characterizesall <strong>parks</strong> serves to buttress their enclave-typecharacter. This suggests that if location on a<strong>science</strong> park is not that imp<strong>or</strong>tant an input f<strong>or</strong>innovation, its imp<strong>or</strong>tance to tenant firms may liein the status and prestige effect that it generates.M<strong>or</strong>e specifically, this maj<strong>or</strong> hypothesis is testedvia an examination <strong>of</strong> those interactions andrelationships (both direct and indirect) that existbetween <strong>science</strong> park location, innovation andvarious characteristics likely to relate to the firm’sinnovation level and associated with the seedbedfunction in a behavioural sense (f<strong>or</strong> example,relationship with universities, spin-<strong>of</strong>f hist<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong>the firm, education and w<strong>or</strong>k experience <strong>of</strong> theentrepreneur <strong>or</strong> manager). Thus, in relation tothe innovation level <strong>of</strong> the firm, we would expectto find the CEO’s educational background anduniversity linkages <strong>related</strong> to the level <strong>of</strong> innovation.This would illustrate the classic humancapital influences on innovation. If the <strong>science</strong>park fulfils a seedbed function f<strong>or</strong> innovativeactivity, then we would expect to find <strong>science</strong> parklocation <strong>related</strong> directly and indirectly to thesecharacteristics and to others such as CEO w<strong>or</strong>kexperience, firm’s spin-<strong>of</strong>f hist<strong>or</strong>y etc. Conversely,absence <strong>of</strong> these relationships would suggest theenclave function <strong>of</strong> the <strong>science</strong> park.5. Data and method5.1. DataThe data source f<strong>or</strong> the empirical analysis thatfollows is a questionnaire survey <strong>of</strong> 162 Israelihigh-technology firms. The survey endeavoured tocover all firms located on the three target <strong>science</strong><strong>parks</strong> (some 110 firms). In practice, responseswere received from 73 firms (66% <strong>of</strong> the targetpopulation). The remainder <strong>of</strong> the firms weredrawn on a stratified basis from <strong>of</strong>f-park locationsin the vicinity <strong>of</strong> the <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> (the Herzliya,Petach Tikva and Holon industrial zones f<strong>or</strong><strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> in the Tel Aviv metropolitan area),the various industrial zones in Jerusalem f<strong>or</strong> theTechnovation Vol. 14 No. 2 99


0. Felsensteinpark in that city and a further group <strong>of</strong> ‘other’(generally metropolitan) locations (Table 1).On a sect<strong>or</strong>al basis, we can point to a certainlevel <strong>of</strong> local specialization (Table 1). Thus, firmsin the Tel Aviv area would seem to be concentratedin the electronics and s<strong>of</strong>tware sect<strong>or</strong>s while theRehovot area is characterized by a large collection<strong>of</strong> biotechnology and chemical firms and Jerusalemby chemicals, electronics and electro-optics. Ineach location, the sect<strong>or</strong>al composition <strong>of</strong> on- and<strong>of</strong>f-park firms is very similar, as are their industrialand employment characteristics.The industrial and employment pr<strong>of</strong>ile <strong>of</strong> thesurveyed firms is outlined in Table 2. As theaverage figures belie the imp<strong>or</strong>tance <strong>of</strong> the smallfirm sect<strong>or</strong> in the sample, the means f<strong>or</strong> this subgroupare presented separately. Small independentfirms f<strong>or</strong>m the vast maj<strong>or</strong>ity <strong>of</strong> the sample (65%<strong>of</strong> firms surveyed have less than 50 employees and67% are <strong>of</strong> independent ownership). In generalthey are younger and m<strong>or</strong>e technology intensivein terms <strong>of</strong> inputs (percentage <strong>of</strong> R&D employees,R&D expenditures etc.) but, as expected, lesscapital intensive and production <strong>or</strong>iented.In the present analysis, approximately 12% <strong>of</strong>responses were incomplete in one way <strong>or</strong> another,leaving a total <strong>of</strong> 142 usable responses. Theseprovided data relating to (a) firm characteristicsand (b) the characteristics <strong>of</strong> the entrepreneurs <strong>or</strong>managers <strong>of</strong> the firms surveyed. In most cases theowner-manager <strong>of</strong> the firm was interviewed. Failingthat, the data relate to the characteristics <strong>of</strong> theseni<strong>or</strong> company executive that responded to thequestionnaire. All the data used are categ<strong>or</strong>icaland the variables are defined in Table 3.Firm characteristics refer here to the firm’slocation, innovation level, location <strong>of</strong> main markets,level <strong>of</strong> interaction with university and spin<strong>of</strong>fantecedents. Entrepreneur/manager characteristicsdescribe the education level and w<strong>or</strong>k experience<strong>of</strong> the firm’s owner-manager and also theextent to which the entrepreneur <strong>or</strong> manager isengaged in production <strong>of</strong> products with which hehas pri<strong>or</strong> experience.In view <strong>of</strong> the relatively limited number ‘<strong>of</strong>observations and the prospect <strong>of</strong> empty cells whenusing n-dimensional cross-tabulations, the variablesabove have been coded into a minimal number <strong>of</strong>TABLE 1. Location and sect<strong>or</strong>al composition <strong>of</strong> firms surveyedn % % located % % % % optical % % Totalon chemicals and electrical and transp<strong>or</strong>tation and s<strong>of</strong>tware other<strong>science</strong> pharma- electronic equipment3 precision engineering’ branchespark ceuticals’ equipment* equipment’Tel Aviv Metropolitan Area 62 39.0 24.0 2.3 52.3 4.6 20.5 20.3 100(Herzliya, TA, Petach Tikva)Rehovot 36 22.0 91.0 39.3 35.1 10.7 10.7 3.6 100(Nes Ziona and Rehovot)Jerusalem 35 21.0 52.0 30.5 30.8 3.8 23.1 7.7 4.1 looelsewhere 29 18.0 15.8 45.3 4.5 2.3 12.4 19.7 looTOTAL 162 100‘Includes Israeli 3-digit SIC codes: 200 (basic chemicals), 201 (pharmaceuticals), 204 & 205 (paints, varnishes, insecticides, fungicides).-‘Includes Israeli 3digit SIC codes: 250 (electrical mot<strong>or</strong>s, transf<strong>or</strong>mers), 251 (electrical equipment), 255 & 256 (communications equipment, electronicequipment f<strong>or</strong> control, scientific and medical uses).‘Includes Israeli Migit SIC codes: 262 & 263 (aircraft parts and Sight control equipment).‘Includes Israeli 3-digit SIC codes: 280 & 2SfJ (scientific measuring and controlling instruments, optical instruments and photographic equipment).51ncludes Israeli 3-digit SIC codes: 733 & 738 (data processing and research consultancies).100 Technovation Vol. 14 No. 2


Science <strong>parks</strong> - seedbeds <strong>or</strong> enclaves <strong>of</strong> innovation?TABLE 2. Industrial and employment characteristics <strong>of</strong> surveyed firmsage <strong>of</strong> 8rm (years)no. <strong>of</strong> employees% academics% technicians% skilled labour% non-skilled labour% female labour% R&D employees% productionFirm characteristics(alI firms)revenue per employee (ThS)% exp<strong>or</strong>tscapital stock per employee (ThS)wages as % total expenditureraw materials as % total expenditureR&D expenditure as % <strong>of</strong> salesN Mean C.V.’ Mean <strong>of</strong> smaUfirms (


Science <strong>parks</strong> - seedbeds <strong>or</strong> enclaves <strong>of</strong> innovation?PROFILEAFig. 1. Innovation pr<strong>of</strong>iles based on entrepreneurs’ education level (E), university linkage ((I) and innovation level <strong>of</strong> firm (I).FGHnot significant). Seventy-five percent <strong>of</strong> firms haveno high-level linkage to universities at all, althougha PhD-level background does seem to breed somef<strong>or</strong>m <strong>of</strong> interaction (over half the companiesfounded by PhDs have intensive connections withuniversities).This low-key relationship, however, could beindicative <strong>of</strong> the generally low-level interactionbetween university and industry existing in Israelthat has been alluded to in other studies [45, 461.This is grounded in the fact that university research(even in an applied f<strong>or</strong>m) is <strong>of</strong>ten not ‘ripe’ enoughto be taken up by industry. In addition, academicresearch is unaware <strong>of</strong> the true problems facingindustry, and industry does not always want t<strong>or</strong>eveal these problems to academia. Only when theuniversity engages in industrial ‘troubleshooting’(generally in the field <strong>of</strong> applied scientific services)does it meet industry’s needs. Industry, f<strong>or</strong> its part,has a conservative attitude to funding universityresearch (conditioned by a sh<strong>or</strong>tage <strong>of</strong> capital)and wants immediate results. The upshot is thatthe university-industry relations that do exist arerather limited, especially in terms <strong>of</strong> intensiverelations such as joint research and funding [47].In general, the simple distribution outlined inFig. 1 seems to suggest that high-level educationalbackground does not say very much about theability to exploit innovations commercially. Furtherm<strong>or</strong>e,the level <strong>of</strong> interaction with universitiesis generally low, and where this interaction doesexist, it results in only marginally m<strong>or</strong>e innovativefirms; one-quarter <strong>of</strong> all firms with intense universityconnections are ‘significant’ innovat<strong>or</strong>s asagainst 21% <strong>of</strong> firms with low-level connections.Putting these relationships in a log-linear framew<strong>or</strong>k,we arrive at similar conclusions. The reduced-f<strong>or</strong>mmodel <strong>of</strong> the 3-way cross-tabulationbetween the variables in Fig. 1 results in thefollowing equationln(M,J = a + YEi + Y”j + ?lk(30*09/l) (7*51/l) (9-39/l)(i, j, k = 1,0)+ YEI,, f YEUij(1*96/l) (544/l)where ln(M& = the expected cell frequency,a = overall mean <strong>of</strong> the log <strong>of</strong> expected cellfrequencies, YEi = effect attributable to the ithTechnovation Vol. 14 No. 2 103


D. Felsensteincateg<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong> education, rU_ = effect attributableto the jth categ<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong> university interaction,yZ, = effect attributable to the kth categ<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong>innovation level, y,?& = effect attributable to theinteraction between the ith categ<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong> educationand the kth categ<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong> innovation level, andyEVij = effect attributable to the interactionbetween the ith categ<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong> education and the jthcateg<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong> university interaction.Figures in parentheses are chi-square statisticsand degrees <strong>of</strong> freedom, all significant at thep < O-05 level, except f<strong>or</strong> the TEZik term that wasf<strong>or</strong>ced into the model.Likelihood ratio chi-square value f<strong>or</strong> estimatedmodel = 4.64 (p = O-0106, 2 degrees <strong>of</strong> freedom).This is the most parsimonious model fitted tothe data. While it shows that education, universitylinkage and innovation are all significant in theirown right, f<strong>or</strong> our purposes the interaction effectsare <strong>of</strong> greater interest. Although the second-<strong>or</strong>derrelationship between university interaction andeducation level <strong>of</strong> the entrepreneur/manager issignificant, this does not necessarily lead to innovativeactivity (the E*I relationship is not significant,but was f<strong>or</strong>ced into the model). The third-<strong>or</strong>derinteraction E*Z*U is also not significant. All thiswould seem to suggest that the ability to realizethe commercial potential <strong>of</strong> innovations (throughestablishing an innovative firm) is not necessarily<strong>related</strong> to academic education <strong>or</strong> university linkage.Success in innovation and its commercial exploitation(i.e. the ability to sell the innovation andkeep the firm going on this basis) are probably<strong>related</strong> to other supply conditions (such as theentrepreneur’s w<strong>or</strong>k hist<strong>or</strong>y and experience) andresult from demand fact<strong>or</strong>s such as market structure(f<strong>or</strong>eign <strong>or</strong> local, barriers to entry and so on).An exhaustive examination <strong>of</strong> these fact<strong>or</strong>s isbeyond the scope <strong>of</strong> this analysis, but a curs<strong>or</strong>yexamination <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> these fact<strong>or</strong>s does notyield any significant relationships. Supply fact<strong>or</strong>s,taken here as entrepreneur’s w<strong>or</strong>k experience asmeasured by the relationship between presentproduct and previous product experience (P),show no significant relationship to innovation.This holds true even when this relationship isstratified by previous employment position (R&Dvs. sales/administration/production). This wasexpected to add a further dimension to the depth<strong>of</strong> w<strong>or</strong>k experience, but the x2 statistics are allinsignificant. Market fact<strong>or</strong>s, as measured by thelocation <strong>of</strong> main market (f<strong>or</strong>eign <strong>or</strong> local) (M),where f<strong>or</strong>eign markets are expected to be m<strong>or</strong>einnovative, competitive and with higher entrybarriers, also yield no significant relationship toinnovation. However, there is a confounding effecthere with innovation and location, which will bediscussed below.6.2. Seedbed effects and <strong>science</strong> parklocationNearly half the firms surveyed here are locatedon <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>. This begs the question as towhether there is any significant difference ininnovative activity between on- and <strong>of</strong>f-park firms( i.e., does the park have a seedbed effect?) andwhether this relationship is confounded by anyother fact<strong>or</strong>s. In view <strong>of</strong> the popular perception <strong>of</strong>the <strong>science</strong> park as facilitating university-industryinteraction, and in the light <strong>of</strong> the paucity <strong>of</strong>empirical evidence supp<strong>or</strong>ting this claim, it isimp<strong>or</strong>tant to try to gauge the imp<strong>or</strong>tance <strong>of</strong> <strong>science</strong>park location in the innovation process.When turning to the features associated withlocation on a <strong>science</strong> park (and presumed toenhance innovative activity), the most obviousstarting-point is university interaction. In commonwith the many studies cited earlier, this is foundto be low amongst all <strong>science</strong> park firms surveyed.High-level interactions (joint research and industryfunding <strong>of</strong> university research) were rep<strong>or</strong>ted by13% and 9% <strong>of</strong> firms respectively. Mid-levelinteractions are not much m<strong>or</strong>e prevalent, withreceipt <strong>of</strong> university consultancy services rep<strong>or</strong>tedby less than 20% <strong>of</strong> <strong>science</strong> park firms, and keyemployees holding faculty positions rep<strong>or</strong>ted byonly 8%. As expected, low-level interactions basedon recruitment <strong>of</strong> local university graduates (28%)and use <strong>of</strong> university facilities (24%) were m<strong>or</strong>euniversal. This pattern, while not illustrating particularlyhigh-level interactions, was nevertheless104 Technovation Vol. 14 No. 2


Science <strong>parks</strong> - seedbeds <strong>or</strong> enclaves <strong>of</strong> innovation?significantly different to that observed f<strong>or</strong> non<strong>science</strong>park firms (x2 = 3.947, p = O-047).If <strong>science</strong> park firms have higher level interactionswith universities, does this result in technologytransfer and, as a consequence, high levels <strong>of</strong>innovation (the ‘seedbed’ hypothesis)? This causalrelationship is not particularly significant(x2 = 2.438, p = 0.118). However, the possibilitydoes exist that the relationship is mediated throughthe effect <strong>of</strong> some other fact<strong>or</strong>. As illustratedabove, innovation is inter<strong>related</strong> with inf<strong>or</strong>mationand much <strong>of</strong> this flows through channels that aregrounded in w<strong>or</strong>k experience, academic educationand the like. In this instance, theref<strong>or</strong>e, we testf<strong>or</strong> the interrelationship between the fact<strong>or</strong>s <strong>science</strong>park location (L), innovation level <strong>of</strong> the firm (Z)and w<strong>or</strong>k experience <strong>of</strong> the entrepreneur/manager(w).These relationships are depicted in Fig. 2. Ascan be seen, no clear pattern can be observed f<strong>or</strong>the relationship between innovation and <strong>science</strong>park agglomeration. When adding the w<strong>or</strong>k experiencedimension, we arrive at a series <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>iles.The conventional path is represented by pr<strong>of</strong>ileA; an entrepreneur with a background in R&Dsets up a high-tech firm producing unique productson a <strong>science</strong> park. This development traject<strong>or</strong>y,however, accounts f<strong>or</strong> only 5% <strong>of</strong> all firmssurveyed. The maj<strong>or</strong>ity <strong>of</strong> <strong>science</strong> park firms(nearly 70%) fall into pr<strong>of</strong>ile G, which representsthe <strong>science</strong> park firm engaged in the productionand modification <strong>of</strong> existing products and foundedby an entrepreneur from a non-R&D background.When stratifying the relationship between <strong>science</strong>park and innovation by w<strong>or</strong>k experience, wefind that the seedbed hypothesis can be upheldindependently <strong>of</strong> w<strong>or</strong>k experience. Thus, f<strong>or</strong>firm founders with an ‘R&D background, thisrelationship is marginally significant (x’ = 2.93,p = 0.083). F<strong>or</strong> entrepreneurs with technical andproduction backgrounds this relationship is slightlystronger (x2 = 5.99, p = O-013). This suggests thatw<strong>or</strong>k experience might have a direct input intothe innovation capabilities <strong>of</strong> the firm (i.e. through‘learning by doing’ [48]). If this experience istechnical and managerial, this could lead to m<strong>or</strong>ecommercially viable innovative products than thoseproduced by firms where the main entrepreneurshave an R&D <strong>or</strong>ientation. In other w<strong>or</strong>ds, commerciallyexploitable innovations call f<strong>or</strong> m<strong>or</strong>e than justPROFILEABCDEFGHFig. 2. Firm pr<strong>of</strong>iles based on entrepreneur’s wbrk background (w), innovation level <strong>of</strong> the firm (l) and <strong>science</strong> park location (IL.).Technovation Vol. 14 No. 2 105


D. Felsensteintechnological prowess and innovation prompted by <strong>science</strong> park location, this latter fact<strong>or</strong> can servesupply-push conditions.to entrench existing seedbed interactions.The complete system <strong>of</strong> these interrelationships The question now arises as to whether otheris examined m<strong>or</strong>e f<strong>or</strong>mally in the log-linear model. fact<strong>or</strong>s exist that could impact on location. AreThe reduced-f<strong>or</strong>m model <strong>of</strong> the relationships other seedbed-promoting processes <strong>related</strong> to scibetweenW, I and L takes the f<strong>or</strong>mln(M,iJ = (Y + YWi t YZj + rWZij(18*18/l) (853/l) (4.5411)(i,Z, k = 1,O)+ YWZLij~(8*14/l)where ln(Mij,) = the expected cell frequency, OL= overall mean <strong>of</strong> the log <strong>of</strong> expected cellfrequencies, yWi = effect attributable to theith categ<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong> w<strong>or</strong>k experience, YZj = effectattributable to the jth categ<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong> innovation level,YWZij = effect attributable to the interactionbetween the ith categ<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong> w<strong>or</strong>k experience andthe jth categ<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong> innovation level, and YWZL,,= effect attributable to the third-<strong>or</strong>der interactionbetween the ith categ<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong> w<strong>or</strong>k experience, thejth categ<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong> innovation and the kth categ<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong>location.Figures in parentheses are chi-square statisticsand degrees <strong>of</strong> freedom, all significant at thep < O-05 level.Likelihood ratio chi-square value f<strong>or</strong> estimatedmodel = 5.76 (p = 0.0461,3 degrees <strong>of</strong> freedom).The results show that only one second-<strong>or</strong>derand one third-<strong>or</strong>der interaction term are significant.Both these terms express the interaction effects<strong>of</strong> w<strong>or</strong>k experience with innovation. There wouldthus seem to be an inf<strong>or</strong>mation flow basedon employment background that is <strong>related</strong> toinnovation level. This also interacts with location,suggesting that while w<strong>or</strong>k experience is <strong>related</strong>to innovation this may be contingent on location.However, this latter three-way interaction is theonly way in which location shows up in the results.All the two-way interactions that include locationare not ‘significant, and even the direct effect <strong>of</strong><strong>science</strong> park location by itself is not included inthe model. All this would seem to imply that whilethe seedbed effect is not necessarily contingent onence park location? As noted earlier, the spin-<strong>of</strong>fprocess is <strong>of</strong>ten associated with spatial clustering,the assumption being that spin-<strong>of</strong>f firms remain inthe local area once they have broken away andcontinue to interact f<strong>or</strong>mally (e.g. subcontracting)<strong>or</strong> inf<strong>or</strong>mally (social exchange) with their f<strong>or</strong>merplaces <strong>of</strong> employment [49].Amongst the firms surveyed, the pattern <strong>of</strong>spin-<strong>of</strong>f was distributed across: (1) local firms,both Israeli and local f<strong>or</strong>eign subsidiaries (36%<strong>of</strong> firms attributable to this source); (2) f<strong>or</strong>eigncompanies abroad (22%); (3) universities (nearlyall local) (26%); and (4) the defence industry(including f<strong>or</strong>mer army <strong>of</strong>ficers) and a ‘miscellaneous’categ<strong>or</strong>y (16%). This distribution highlightedthe relatively large number <strong>of</strong> firms thathave spun-out <strong>of</strong> f<strong>or</strong>eign companies abroad. W<strong>or</strong>kexperience abroad would seem to expose thepotential entrepreneur to the possibilities <strong>of</strong> settingup an independent operation. It could also be thatnew firms starting up in this way have a guaranteedmarket in the f<strong>or</strong>m <strong>of</strong> their f<strong>or</strong>mer company. Thismitigates some <strong>of</strong> the risk generally involved inspinning-<strong>of</strong>f [49].A significant relationship is found to existbetween spin-<strong>of</strong>f (P) and <strong>science</strong> park location(L) (x2 = 4@07, p = 0X)451). However, whenstratifying the relationship between innovationand location by type <strong>of</strong> spin-<strong>of</strong>f, no significantrelationship exists. This would seem to show thatthe (rather weak) relationship between innovationand location, outlined above, is not contingent onthe type <strong>of</strong> spin-<strong>of</strong>f. Thus, unlike the case f<strong>or</strong>w<strong>or</strong>k experience, we cannot conclusively say thatf<strong>or</strong>mer companies are an apparent source <strong>of</strong> inputthat will influence the firm’s innovation level. Assuch, there does not seem to be any reasonf<strong>or</strong> conscious <strong>science</strong>-park clustering <strong>of</strong> spin-<strong>of</strong>fsaround ‘incubat<strong>or</strong>’ <strong>or</strong>ganizations. They might clusterdue to inertia, prestige considerations associatedwith the location <strong>or</strong> simply through lack <strong>of</strong>106 Technovation Vol. ?4 No. 2


Science <strong>parks</strong> - seedbeds <strong>or</strong> enclaves <strong>of</strong> innovation?inf<strong>or</strong>mation about alternative locations. However,we have little evidence to suggest that they clusterf<strong>or</strong> inf<strong>or</strong>mation and interaction purposes <strong>or</strong> that theincubat<strong>or</strong> <strong>or</strong>ganization is an inherent component <strong>of</strong>the seedbed effect. In addition, the surprisinglyhigh number <strong>of</strong> spin-<strong>of</strong>fs attributable to f<strong>or</strong>eignfirms, thereby discounting the option <strong>of</strong> locationalclustering around incubat<strong>or</strong>s, would seem to supp<strong>or</strong>tthis contention.Type <strong>of</strong> market (M) (exp<strong>or</strong>t <strong>or</strong> local) washypothesized as exerting an influence on innovationlevel. Here we address the issue <strong>of</strong> whether firmswith similar markets are likely to choose a <strong>science</strong>park f<strong>or</strong> its seedbed effect. On the basis <strong>of</strong>firms surveyed, there is no evidence <strong>of</strong> a directrelationship between <strong>science</strong> park location (L) andmarket <strong>or</strong>ientation (M). However, the relationshipbetween type <strong>of</strong> location and innovation level isagain mediated by type <strong>of</strong> market. Thus, f<strong>or</strong> firmsoperating in local markets this relationship exists(x2 = 6.397, p = O-012), while it is not apparentf<strong>or</strong> firms serving exp<strong>or</strong>t markets. In view <strong>of</strong> therelationship between market and innovation level,this might suggest that f<strong>or</strong> those firms operatingin local markets <strong>science</strong> park clustering as aninteraction strategy is m<strong>or</strong>e imp<strong>or</strong>tant than f<strong>or</strong>firms operating abroad. The latter probably havealternative inf<strong>or</strong>mation netw<strong>or</strong>ks connected withtheir markets and are thus less contingent on the<strong>science</strong> park and its seedbed effects.7. ConclusionsThis paper has examined the case f<strong>or</strong> theexistence <strong>of</strong> seedbed conditions on <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>that promote innovation. The basic questions thatthe paper attempts to answer are, first, whetherthese effects are an imp<strong>or</strong>tant input to the firm’sinnovation level and, second, the extent to whichthese effects are contingent on the physical proximityand clustering aff<strong>or</strong>ded by the <strong>science</strong> park.The evidence seems to indicate that the inf<strong>or</strong>mationflows and knowledge netw<strong>or</strong>ks associatedwith university interaction and an entrepreneur’seducation level do not necessarily translate intoinnovation. We suggest that the influences oninnovation might lie somewhere else: in bothsupply conditions (such as the w<strong>or</strong>k experience <strong>of</strong>the entrepreneur) and the structure <strong>of</strong> demand(market conditions). Thus, the results presentedin this paper provide further supp<strong>or</strong>t f<strong>or</strong> theargument in much <strong>of</strong> the business literature to theeffect that technical knowledge without businessskill does not necessarily make f<strong>or</strong> innovativelysuccessful products <strong>or</strong> firms [l, 2, 501. To this wemust add that the particular nature <strong>of</strong> hightechnologymarkets (competition, imperfect knowledgeat the early stages and high barriers to entryat later stages) also means that the inf<strong>or</strong>mationnetw<strong>or</strong>ks likely to arise on the basis <strong>of</strong> universityinteraction and educational level are not necessarilythose needed f<strong>or</strong> innovation (in contrast toinvention).The ‘seedbed’ hypothesis, that f<strong>or</strong>ms the centralfocus <strong>of</strong> this paper, is supp<strong>or</strong>ted only undercertain conditions. In common with other empiricalevidence [6, 35, 39, 401, the level <strong>of</strong> interactionbetween firms located on <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> and localuniversities is generally low. It is higher, however,than the level <strong>of</strong> interaction exhibited by companiesthat are not <strong>science</strong> park tenants. This <strong>of</strong> itself,however, is no indication <strong>of</strong> a seedbed effectarising from <strong>science</strong> park location. Testing thisproposition m<strong>or</strong>e directly, we find that thelocation-innovation connection is strengthenedwhen stratified by w<strong>or</strong>k experience. This wouldseem to indicate that <strong>science</strong> park location, ratherthan being seedbed-inducing, could be seedbedentrenching.In common with other studies, wehave suggested that the choice <strong>of</strong> a <strong>science</strong> parklocation is due as much to the status and prestigeeffect that these exclusive locations confer [5, 11,351, as it is to the perceived benefits in terms<strong>of</strong> innovative edge. Science park location couldtheref<strong>or</strong>e be the outcome <strong>of</strong> a process <strong>of</strong> ‘socialsignalling’ and ‘swarming’ [ 171.The policy implications <strong>of</strong> these findings suggestthat alternative vehicles f<strong>or</strong> technology transfer,university-industry interaction and inter-firm flows<strong>of</strong> inf<strong>or</strong>mation and materials need to be developed.Universities are slowly beginning to developTechnovation Vol. 14 No. 2 107


D. Felsensteininnovative new f<strong>or</strong>ms <strong>of</strong> relations with industry,based on alternative technology transfer mechanismsand synergistic relationships such as limitedpartnerships, R&D seed funds and generic researchcollab<strong>or</strong>ation [31, 461. Firms are expl<strong>or</strong>ing newchannels f<strong>or</strong> cooperation, alliances, netw<strong>or</strong>k f<strong>or</strong>mationand diagonal integration in an attempt todisperse risk, cope with technological complexityand in reaction to perceived external threats [51].Faced with the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the task <strong>of</strong> innovation,appendixing to the <strong>science</strong> park the role <strong>of</strong>innovation ‘seedbed’ <strong>or</strong> regional development‘growth pole’ may be an unrealistic expectationfrom a project that in many instances is not muchm<strong>or</strong>e than a real-estate development. Thus, ifthere is some disappointment in the fact that<strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> are <strong>of</strong>ten not much m<strong>or</strong>e thanhigh-tech ‘islands’ with minimal interactions bothbetween themselves and with their neighbouringuniversities, it could be that hopes were pitchedtoo high in the first place.From the public policy perspective, the ‘seedbed’metaph<strong>or</strong> allows <strong>of</strong>ficials and policy makers tooperationalize their expectations <strong>of</strong> <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>.Therein lies its appeal. The <strong>science</strong> park is, <strong>of</strong>course, just one <strong>of</strong> a collection <strong>of</strong> policy instrumentsthat aim to encourage the development <strong>of</strong> seedbeds<strong>of</strong> innovation. However, it is <strong>of</strong>ten uncriticallyaccepted as such - a position that this paper hassought to re-evaluate. While, f<strong>or</strong> didactic purposes,we have characterized <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong> in terms <strong>of</strong> aan enclave/seedbed dichotomy, in reality most <strong>of</strong>them probably lie somewhere along the continuumrunning between these two polar positions. Thechallenge theref<strong>or</strong>e lies in the development <strong>of</strong>policy tools that will encourage them to developinto m<strong>or</strong>e than just a ‘collection <strong>of</strong> firms’.AcknowledgementsFunding f<strong>or</strong> this research was supp<strong>or</strong>ted in partby a grant from the Israel Trustees Foundation.The w<strong>or</strong>k was completed while the auth<strong>or</strong> was avisiting scholar at the Center f<strong>or</strong> Urban Affairsand Policy Research, N<strong>or</strong>thwestern <strong>University</strong>,Evanston, Illinois, USA, and in receipt <strong>of</strong> a grantfrom the Lady Davis Fellowship Trust.Notes’ All these effects exist, <strong>of</strong> course, over and abovethe regular income, employment and output effects <strong>of</strong>universities on local economic growth. On this issue,research has shown a particularly pr<strong>of</strong>ound effect onlocal service sect<strong>or</strong>s induced by university purchasing,staff and student expenditures [23,24]. Impact studies <strong>of</strong>individual universities have reached similar conclusionsalthough methodologies and consequently outputs varygreatly (see f<strong>or</strong> example [25-271).2 In contrast, scientists and engineers as a percentage<strong>of</strong> the total <strong>science</strong> park labour f<strong>or</strong>ce are rep<strong>or</strong>ted as23% in the case <strong>of</strong> the <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> Utah Researchpark, 31% f<strong>or</strong> Research Triangle Park and 33% f<strong>or</strong>Stanf<strong>or</strong>d Research Park [ll].3 Braun and McHone [37] rep<strong>or</strong>t income, output,employment and value-added multipliers f<strong>or</strong> <strong>science</strong>park firms located on the Central Fl<strong>or</strong>ida ResearchPark. These lie in the range <strong>of</strong> 1~59-1~87. Interestingly,multipliers f<strong>or</strong> Central Fl<strong>or</strong>ida firms <strong>of</strong>f-park are generallyhigher, ranging from 1.65 to 2.07.4 This ratio (~5~) is defined aswhere h4, = observed frequencies in each cell, andticijkj = expected frequencies in each cell.ReferencesA.C. Cooper, The role <strong>of</strong> incubat<strong>or</strong> <strong>or</strong>ganizationsin the founding <strong>of</strong> growth-<strong>or</strong>iented firms. Journal <strong>of</strong>Business Venturing, 1 (1985) 75-86.A.C. Cooper and W.C. Dunkelberg, Entrepreneurshipand paths to business ownership. StrategicManagement Journal, 7 (1986) 53-68.R.N. Cox, Lessons from 30 years <strong>of</strong> <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>in the USA. In: J.M. Gibb (ed.), Science Parks andInnovation Centres: Their Economic and SocialImpact. Elsevier Science Publications, Amsterdam,1985, pp. 17-25.R. Miller and M. Cote, Growing the next SiliconValley, Harvard Business Review, 63(4) (1985)114-123.108Technovation Vol. 14 No. 2


Science <strong>parks</strong> - seedbeds <strong>or</strong> enclaves <strong>of</strong> innovation?5 R.A. Joseph, Silicon Valley myth and the <strong>or</strong>igins <strong>of</strong> REI W<strong>or</strong>king Papers Series, Center f<strong>or</strong> Regionaltechnology <strong>parks</strong> in Australia. Science and Public Economic Issues, Case Western <strong>University</strong>, Cleve-Policy, 16 (1989) 353-365. land, OH, 1990.6 D. Massey, P. Quintas and D. Wield, High TechFantasies: Science Parks in Society, Science andSpace. Routledge, London, 1992.7 R. Struyk and F. James, Intra-Metropolitan IndustrialLocation. Lexington Books, Lexington, MA, 1975.8 I.G. Begg and G.C. Cameron, High technologylocation and the urban areas <strong>of</strong> Great Britain. UrbanStudies, 25 (1988) 361-379.9 E.J. Davelaar and P. Nijkamp, The role <strong>of</strong> themetropolitan milieu as an incubation centre f<strong>or</strong>technological innovations: a Dutch case-study. UrbanStudies, 26 (1989) 517-525.10 M.T. Peddle, An empirical investigation <strong>of</strong> therelationship between community characteristics andthe presence <strong>of</strong> industrial <strong>parks</strong>. Regional SciencePerspectives, 18(2) (1988) 14-28.11 M.I. Luger and H.A. Goldstein, Technology in theGarden, Research Parks and Regional EconomicDevelopment. <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> N<strong>or</strong>th Carolina Press,Chapel Hill, NC, 1991.12 A.J. Scott and M. St<strong>or</strong>per, High technology industryand regional development: a the<strong>or</strong>etical critique andreconstruction. International Social Science Journal,112 (1987) 215-233.13 P. Aydalot and D. Keeble, High Technology Industryand Innovative Environments: The European Experience.Routledge, London, 1988.14 R. Camagni, Local ‘milieu’, uncertainty and innovationnetw<strong>or</strong>ks: towards a new dynamic the<strong>or</strong>y <strong>of</strong>economic space. In: R. Camagni (ed.), InnovationNetw<strong>or</strong>ks; Spatial Perspectives. Belhaven, London,1991, pp. 121-144.15 Z.J. Acs and D.B. Audretsch, Innovation and SmallFirms, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1990.16 S. Birley, The role <strong>of</strong> netw<strong>or</strong>ks in the entrepreneurialprocess. Journal <strong>of</strong> Business Venturing, 1 (1985)107-117.17 S.J. Appold, The location process <strong>of</strong> industrialresearch lab<strong>or</strong>at<strong>or</strong>ies. Annals <strong>of</strong> Regional Science,25 (1991) 137-144.18 A. Jaffe, Technological opp<strong>or</strong>tunity and spillovers<strong>of</strong> R&D: evidence from firms’ patents, pr<strong>of</strong>its andmarket value. American Economic Review, 76 (1986)984-1001..19 N. Bania, R. Eberts and M.S. Fogarty, Universitiesand rhe Start-Up <strong>of</strong> New Companies: Can weGeneralize from Route 128 and Silicon Valley?20 P. Beeson and E. Montgomery, The Effects <strong>of</strong>Colleges and Universities on Local Lab<strong>or</strong> Markets.NBER W<strong>or</strong>king Paper No. 3280, Cambridge, MA,1990.21 N. Bania, L.N. Calkins and D.R. Dalenberg, Theeffects <strong>of</strong> regional <strong>science</strong> and technology policy onthe geographical distribution <strong>of</strong> industrial R&Dlab<strong>or</strong>at<strong>or</strong>ies. Journal <strong>of</strong> Regional Science, 32(2)(1992) 209-228.22 N. Bania, M.S. Fogarty and S. Kaufman, AnAssessment <strong>of</strong> Cleveland’s Scientific and EngineeringBase and its Role in the Economy. Center f<strong>or</strong>Regional Economic Issues, Case Western Reserve<strong>University</strong>, Cleveland, OH, 1987.23 D. Steinnes, On understanding and evaluating theuniversity’s evolving economic development policy.Economic Development Quarterly, l(2) (1987)214-223.24 D.W. Hedrick, S.E. Henson and R.S. Mack, Theeffects <strong>of</strong> universities on local retail, service andFIRE employment: some cross-sectional evidence.Growth and Change, 21(3) (1990) 9-20.25 M. Brownrigg, The economic impact <strong>of</strong> a newuniversity. Scottish Journal <strong>of</strong> Political Economy,20(20) (1974) 1234-1239.26 H.A. Goldstein, Estimating the regional economicimpact <strong>of</strong> universities: an application <strong>of</strong> input-outputanalysis. Planning f<strong>or</strong> Higher Education, 18(l)(1989-90) 51-63.27 M.F. Bleaney, M.R. Binks, D. Greenaway, G.V.Reed and D.K. Whynes, What does a universityadd to its local economy? Applied Economics, 24(1992) 305-311.28 H. Eto and M. Fujita, Regularities in the growth <strong>of</strong>high technology industries in regions. ResearchPolicy, 18 (1989) 135-153.29 R. Fl<strong>or</strong>ax and H. Folmer, Knowledge impacts <strong>of</strong>universities on industry: an aggregate simultaneousinvestment model. Journal <strong>of</strong> Regional Science, 32(4)(1992) 437-466.30 D.A. Garvin, Spin-<strong>of</strong>fs and the new firm f<strong>or</strong>mationprocess. Calif<strong>or</strong>nia Management Review, 25(2) (1983)3-20.31 A.M. Brett, D.V. Gibson and R.W. Smil<strong>or</strong> (eds.),<strong>University</strong> Spin-Off Companies: Economic Development,Faculty Entrepreneurs and Technology Transfer.Rowan and Littlefield, Savage, MA, 1991.Technovation Vol. 14 No. 2 109


0. Felsenstein32 R. Van Dierdonck, K. Debackere and M.A. Rappa,An assessment <strong>of</strong> <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>: towards a betterunderstanding <strong>of</strong> their role in the diffusion <strong>of</strong>technological knowledge. R&D Management, 21(2)(1991) 109-122.33 S.Q. Wicksteed, Universities, Enterprise and LocalEconomic Development: An Expl<strong>or</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> Links.Manpower Services Commission, HMSO, London,1988.34 A. Shachar and D. Felsenstein, Urban economicdevelopment and high technology industry. UrbanStudies, 29(6) (1992) 839-855.35 S. Macdonald, British <strong>science</strong> <strong>parks</strong>: reflections onthe politics <strong>of</strong> high technology. R&D Management,17(l) (1987) 25-37.36 R. Rothwell and M. Dodgson, External linkagesand innovation in small and medium sized enterprises.R&D Management, 21(2) (1991) 125-137.37 B.M. Braun and W.W. McHone, Science <strong>parks</strong> aseconomic development policy: a case study approach.Economic Development Quarterly, 6(2) (1992)135-147.38 S.Q. Wicksteed, The Cambridge Phenomenon: TheGrowth <strong>of</strong> High Technology Industry in a <strong>University</strong>Town. Segal Quince Wicksteed, Cambridge, 1985.39 G. Steed and D. De Genoa, Ottawa’s technology<strong>or</strong>ientedcomplex. Canadian Geographer, 27(l)(1983) 263-278.40 R.A. Joseph, Technology <strong>parks</strong> and their contributionto the development <strong>of</strong> technology <strong>or</strong>ientedcomplexes in Australia. Environment and PlanningC, 7 (1989) 173-192.41 M.J. Hagey and E.J. Malecki, Linkages in hightechnology industries: a Fl<strong>or</strong>ida case study. Environmentand Planning A, 18 (1986) 1477-1498.42 A. Glasmeier, Fact<strong>or</strong>s governing the development<strong>of</strong> high tech industry agglomerations: a tale <strong>of</strong> threecities. Regional Studies, 22(4) (1988) 287-301.43 State Comptroller, Annual Rep<strong>or</strong>t No. 32. Office <strong>of</strong>the State Comptroller, Government Printing Office,Jerusalem, 1982 (in Hebrew).44 D. Knoke and P. Burke, Log-Linear Models. Sage,Beverly Hills, CA, 1980.45464748495051A. Keynan, Science and Israel’s Future: A Blueprintf<strong>or</strong> Revitalizing Basic Research and StrengtheningScience-Based Industry. Israel Academy <strong>of</strong> Scienceand Humanities and the Jerusalem Institute f<strong>or</strong> IsraelStudies, Jerusalem, 1988.D. Felsenstein, The Role <strong>of</strong> Catalytic Fundingin Promoting <strong>University</strong>-Zndustry Collab<strong>or</strong>ation inApplied Research. Research Rep<strong>or</strong>t No. 6. JerusalemInstitute f<strong>or</strong> Israel Studies, Jerusalem, 1990.I. Bijawi and Y. Raban, The Research System andScience Based Industry in Israel. Research Rep<strong>or</strong>t.Interdisciplinary Centre f<strong>or</strong> Technological F<strong>or</strong>ecastingand Analysis, Tel Aviv <strong>University</strong>, Tel Aviv,1988 (in Hebrew).M.A. Maidique and D.J. Birger, The new productlearning cycle. Research Policy, 14(6) (1985) 299-313.R.W. Smil<strong>or</strong>, D.V. Gibson and G.B. Dietrich,<strong>University</strong> spin-out companies: technology start-upsfrom UT-Austin. Journal <strong>of</strong> Business Venturing, 5(1990) 63-76.M. Cross, New Firm F<strong>or</strong>mation and Regional Development.Gower, Aldershot, UK, 1981.C. De Bresson and F. Amese, Netw<strong>or</strong>ks <strong>of</strong> innovat<strong>or</strong>s:a review and introduction to the issue.Research Policy, 20(5) (1991) 363-380.-_.appeared in journals such asResearch Policy, W<strong>or</strong>ld Development, Regional Studies, UrbanStudies, Small Business Economics and Entrepreneurship andRegional Development. At present he is w<strong>or</strong>king on a methodologyf<strong>or</strong> estimating the knowledge impacts generated byuniversities on their urban and regional economies, and on astudy <strong>of</strong> the netw<strong>or</strong>k potential arising from new f<strong>or</strong>ms <strong>of</strong>university-industry collab<strong>or</strong>ation.110 Technovation Vol. 14 No. 2

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!