12.11.2016 Views

The Climate Surprise

The-Climate-Surprise_CO2C-New-Criterion-1

The-Climate-Surprise_CO2C-New-Criterion-1

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Rethinking climate economics<br />

by Bruce M. Everett<br />

<strong>Climate</strong> policy is primarily a scienfic<br />

issue, but economics has an important<br />

role to play, too. To climate acvists,<br />

economic analysis means cataloguing the<br />

inevitable disasters of an increasingly unlivable<br />

planet. <strong>The</strong> best available science, however,<br />

suggests that carbon dioxide in fact<br />

contributes to human well-being.<br />

If economics is to make a useful contribuon<br />

to the climate discussion, economic analysis<br />

should be aligned with science by following two<br />

principles: first, establish the appropriate base<br />

case for analysis and, second, reflect honestly<br />

and accurately the costs of carbon reducon.<br />

<strong>The</strong> key parameter in the scienfic discussion<br />

is climate sensivity, defined as the<br />

temperature increase that would result from<br />

doubling the atmospheric concentraon of<br />

CO. Carbon dioxide is a greenhouse gas, and<br />

basic physics indicates that the sensivity of<br />

CO by itself would be about degree Celsius.<br />

In its Fih Assessment Report from ,<br />

however, the UN Intergovernmental Panel<br />

on <strong>Climate</strong> Change () esmated equilibrium<br />

climate sensivity in the range of . to<br />

. degrees Celsius. <strong>The</strong> hypothesis of high<br />

climate sensivity was established several<br />

decades ago by climate models that incorporate<br />

feedback effects that amplify warming,<br />

oen with higher humidity assumed to occur<br />

at higher temperatures.<br />

<strong>The</strong> essence of science, however, is the testing<br />

of hypotheses against data. <strong>Climate</strong> models<br />

have been making high sensivity predicons<br />

for a long me, but actual experience to date<br />

shows a sensivity below the boom of the<br />

range. In other words, the models have<br />

consistently overpredicted temperature.<br />

Nonetheless, much of the economic analysis<br />

currently available is not only based on the <br />

range but on the high end of the range. Using<br />

an extreme case as a starng point supports<br />

the narrave of climate acvists, but severely<br />

distorts the analysis.<br />

Macroeconomic forecasts are naturally<br />

subject to a wide range of uncertainty, but it<br />

is important to center the analysis on the most<br />

reasonable and likely set of assumpons. For<br />

example, we do not do our economic planning<br />

on the basis of worldwide depression or nuclear<br />

war. Assuming catastrophe effecvely eliminates<br />

the discipline of cost-benefit analysis. If we are all<br />

going to fry and drown from man-made climate<br />

change, we don’t have to worry about the costs<br />

of reducing carbon or the impacts of climate<br />

policies on peoples’ lives. Yet economic policy<br />

is about costs and trade-offs.<br />

Consider the case of Germany. Among climate<br />

acvists, Germany and Chancellor Angela<br />

Merkl are nothing short of rock stars. In ,<br />

the noted author and columnist Thomas Friedman<br />

wrote in <strong>The</strong> New York Times that Germany<br />

would be Europe’s first “green solar-powered<br />

superpower.” Naonal Geographic magazine,<br />

always a reliable supporter of climate acvism,<br />

seconded Friedman’s claim, telling its<br />

29

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!