23.10.2018 Views

Predatory Lending

Predatory Lending

Predatory Lending

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

The e-Advocate<br />

Monthly<br />

…a Compendium of Works on:<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong><br />

Luke 6:34-36<br />

Proverbs 22:7 | Exodus 22:25<br />

Deuteronomy 23:19; 15:6 | Leviticus 25:36-37<br />

Matthew 5:42<br />

“Helping Individuals, Organizations & Communities<br />

Achieve Their Full Potential”<br />

Special Edition| AF – August 2021


Walk by Faith; Serve with Abandon<br />

Expect to Win!<br />

Page 2 of 181


The Advocacy Foundation, Inc.<br />

Helping Individuals, Organizations & Communities<br />

Achieve Their Full Potential<br />

Since its founding in 2003, The Advocacy Foundation has become recognized as an effective<br />

provider of support to those who receive our services, having real impact within the communities<br />

we serve. We are currently engaged in community and faith-based collaborative initiatives,<br />

having the overall objective of eradicating all forms of youth violence and correcting injustices<br />

everywhere. In carrying-out these initiatives, we have adopted the evidence-based strategic<br />

framework developed and implemented by the Office of Juvenile Justice & Delinquency<br />

Prevention (OJJDP).<br />

The stated objectives are:<br />

1. Community Mobilization;<br />

2. Social Intervention;<br />

3. Provision of Opportunities;<br />

4. Organizational Change and Development;<br />

5. Suppression [of illegal activities].<br />

Moreover, it is our most fundamental belief that in order to be effective, prevention and<br />

intervention strategies must be Community Specific, Culturally Relevant, Evidence-Based, and<br />

Collaborative. The Violence Prevention and Intervention programming we employ in<br />

implementing this community-enhancing framework include the programs further described<br />

throughout our publications, programs and special projects both domestically and<br />

internationally.<br />

www.TheAdvocacy.Foundation<br />

ISBN: ......... ../2017<br />

......... Printed in the USA<br />

Advocacy Foundation Publishers<br />

Philadelphia, PA<br />

(878) 222-0450 | Voice | Data | SMS<br />

Page 3 of 181


Page 4 of 181


Dedication<br />

______<br />

Every publication in our many series’ is dedicated to everyone, absolutely everyone, who by<br />

virtue of their calling and by Divine inspiration, direction and guidance, is on the battlefield dayafter-day<br />

striving to follow God’s will and purpose for their lives. And this is with particular affinity<br />

for those Spiritual warriors who are being transformed into excellence through daily academic,<br />

professional, familial, and other challenges.<br />

We pray that you will bear in mind:<br />

Matthew 19:26 (NLT)<br />

Jesus looked at them intently and said, “Humanly speaking, it is impossible.<br />

But with God everything is possible.” (Emphasis added)<br />

To all of us who daily look past our circumstances, and naysayers, to what the Lord says we will<br />

accomplish:<br />

Blessings!!<br />

- The Advocacy Foundation, Inc.<br />

Page 5 of 181


Page 6 of 181


The Transformative Justice Project<br />

Eradicating Juvenile Delinquency Requires a Multi-Disciplinary Approach<br />

The Juvenile Justice system is incredibly<br />

overloaded, and Solutions-Based programs are<br />

woefully underfunded. Our precious children,<br />

therefore, particularly young people of color, often<br />

get the “swift” version of justice whenever they<br />

come into contact with the law.<br />

Decisions to build prison facilities are often based<br />

on elementary school test results, and our country<br />

incarcerates more of its young than any other<br />

nation on earth. So we at The Foundation labor to<br />

pull our young people out of the “school to prison”<br />

pipeline, and we then coordinate the efforts of the<br />

legal, psychological, governmental and<br />

educational professionals needed to bring an end<br />

to delinquency.<br />

We also educate families, police, local businesses,<br />

elected officials, clergy, and schools and other<br />

stakeholders about transforming whole communities, and we labor to change their<br />

thinking about the causes of delinquency with the goal of helping them embrace the<br />

idea of restoration for the young people in our care who demonstrate repentance for<br />

their<br />

mistakes.<br />

The way we accomplish all this is a follows:<br />

1. We vigorously advocate for charges reductions, wherever possible, in the<br />

adjudicatory (court) process, with the ultimate goal of expungement or pardon, in order<br />

to maximize the chances for our clients to graduate high school and progress into<br />

college, military service or the workforce without the stigma of a criminal record;<br />

2. We then enroll each young person into an Evidence-Based, Data-Driven<br />

Restorative Justice program designed to facilitate their rehabilitation and subsequent<br />

reintegration back into the community;<br />

3. While those projects are operating, we conduct a wide variety of ComeUnity-<br />

ReEngineering seminars and workshops on topics ranging from Juvenile Justice to<br />

Parental Rights, to Domestic issues to Police friendly contacts, to mental health<br />

intervention, to CBO and FBO accountability and compliance;<br />

Page 7 of 181


4. Throughout the process, we encourage and maintain frequent personal contact<br />

between all parties;<br />

5 Throughout the process we conduct a continuum of events and fundraisers<br />

designed to facilitate collaboration among professionals and community stakeholders;<br />

and finally<br />

6. 1 We disseminate Quarterly publications, like our e-Advocate series Newsletter<br />

and our e-Advocate Quarterly electronic Magazine to all regular donors in order to<br />

facilitate a lifelong learning process on the ever-evolving developments in the Justice<br />

system.<br />

And in addition to the help we provide for our young clients and their families, we also<br />

facilitate Community Engagement through the Restorative Justice process,<br />

thereby balancing the interests of local businesses, schools, clergy, social assistance<br />

organizations, elected officials, law enforcement entities, and all interested<br />

stakeholders. Through these efforts, relationships are rebuilt & strengthened, local<br />

businesses and communities are enhanced & protected from victimization, young<br />

careers are developed, and our precious young people are kept out of the prison<br />

pipeline.<br />

Additionally, we develop Transformative “Void Resistance” (TVR) initiatives to elevate<br />

concerns of our successes resulting in economic hardship for those employed by the<br />

penal system.<br />

TVR is an innovative-comprehensive process that works in conjunction with our<br />

Transformative Justice initiatives to transition the original use and purpose of current<br />

systems into positive social impact operations, which systematically retrains current<br />

staff, renovates facilities, creates new employment opportunities, increases salaries and<br />

is data proven to enhance employee’s mental wellbeing and overall quality of life – an<br />

exponential Transformative Social Impact benefit for ALL community stakeholders.<br />

This is a massive undertaking, and we need all the help and financial support you can<br />

give! We plan to help 75 young persons per quarter-year (aggregating to a total of 250<br />

per year) in each jurisdiction we serve) at an average cost of under $2,500 per client,<br />

per year. *<br />

Thank you in advance for your support!<br />

* FYI:<br />

1<br />

In addition to supporting our world-class programming and support services, all regular donors receive our Quarterly e-Newsletter<br />

(The e-Advocate), as well as The e-Advocate Quarterly Magazine.<br />

Page 8 of 181


1. The national average cost to taxpayers for minimum-security youth incarceration,<br />

is around $43,000.00 per child, per year.<br />

2. The average annual cost to taxpayers for maximum-security youth incarceration<br />

is well over $148,000.00 per child, per year.<br />

- (US News and World Report, December 9, 2014);<br />

3. In every jurisdiction in the nation, the Plea Bargain rate is above 99%.<br />

The Judicial system engages in a tri-partite balancing task in every single one of these<br />

matters, seeking to balance Rehabilitative Justice with Community Protection and<br />

Judicial Economy, and, although the practitioners work very hard to achieve positive<br />

outcomes, the scales are nowhere near balanced where people of color are involved.<br />

We must reverse this trend, which is right now working very much against the best<br />

interests of our young.<br />

Our young people do not belong behind bars.<br />

- Jack Johnson<br />

Page 9 of 181


Page 10 of 181


The Advocacy Foundation, Inc.<br />

Helping Individuals, Organizations & Communities<br />

Achieve Their Full Potential<br />

…a compendium of works on<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong><br />

“Turning the Improbable Into the Exceptional”<br />

Atlanta<br />

Philadelphia<br />

______<br />

John C Johnson III<br />

Founder & CEO<br />

(878) 222-0450<br />

Voice | Data | SMS<br />

www.TheAdvocacy.Foundation<br />

Page 11 of 181


Page 12 of 181


Biblical Authority<br />

______<br />

Luke 6:34-36 (NIV)<br />

34<br />

And if you lend to those from whom you expect repayment, what credit is that to<br />

you? Even sinners lend to sinners, expecting to be repaid in full. 35 But love your<br />

enemies, do good to them, and lend to them without expecting to get anything back.<br />

Then your reward will be great, and you will be children of the Most High, because he is<br />

kind to the ungrateful and wicked. 36 Be merciful, just as your Father is merciful.<br />

Proverbs 22:7<br />

7<br />

The rich rule over the poor, and the borrower is slave to the lender.<br />

Exodus 22:25<br />

25<br />

“If you lend money to one of my people among you who is needy, do not treat it like a<br />

business deal; charge no interest.<br />

Deuteronomy 23:19<br />

19<br />

Do not charge a fellow Israelite interest, whether on money or food or anything else<br />

that may earn interest.<br />

Deuteronomy 15:6<br />

6<br />

For the Lord your God will bless you as he has promised, and you will lend to many<br />

nations but will borrow from none. You will rule over many nations but none will rule<br />

over you.<br />

Leviticus 25:36-37<br />

36<br />

Do not take interest or any profit from them, but fear your God, so that they may<br />

continue to live among you. 37 You must not lend them money at interest or sell them<br />

food at a profit.<br />

Matthew 5:42<br />

42<br />

Give to the one who asks you, and do not turn away from the one who wants to<br />

borrow from you.<br />

Page 13 of 181


Page 14 of 181


Table of Contents<br />

…a compilation of works on<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong><br />

Biblical Authority<br />

I. Introduction: <strong>Predatory</strong> and Subprime <strong>Lending</strong>……………………. 17<br />

II.<br />

The Poverty Industry, Economic Inequality,<br />

and Redlining ………………………………………………… 31<br />

III. Aporophobia and Economic Discrimination……………………….. 87<br />

IV. Payday <strong>Lending</strong>………………………………………………………. 95<br />

V. Refund Anticipation <strong>Lending</strong>……….………………………………. 111<br />

VI. Title Loans……………………………………………………………. 117<br />

VII. Loan Sharks………..………………………………………………… 123<br />

VIII. Usury………………………………......……………………………… 133<br />

IX. References……………………………………………………............ 147<br />

______<br />

Attachments<br />

A. What Is <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong>?<br />

B. <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> and The Subprime Crisis<br />

C. Subprime and <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> in Rural America<br />

Copyright © 2018 The Advocacy Foundation, Inc. All Rights Reserved.<br />

Page 15 of 181


This work is not meant to be a piece of original academic<br />

analysis, but rather draws very heavily on the work of<br />

scholars in a diverse range of fields. All material drawn upon<br />

is referenced appropriately.<br />

Page 16 of 181


I. Introduction<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> and Subprime <strong>Lending</strong><br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> is practices at lending organizations during a loan origination<br />

process that are characterized by critics as unfair, deceptive, or fraudulent. While there<br />

are no legal definitions in the United States for predatory lending per se, a 2006 audit<br />

report from the<br />

office of<br />

inspector<br />

general of the<br />

Federal<br />

Deposit<br />

Insurance<br />

Corporation<br />

(FDIC) broadly<br />

defines<br />

predatory<br />

lending as<br />

"imposing<br />

unfair and<br />

abusive loan<br />

terms on<br />

borrowers",<br />

though "unfair"<br />

and "abusive"<br />

were not<br />

specifically defined. Though there are laws against some of the specific practices<br />

commonly identified as predatory, various federal agencies use the phrase as a catchall<br />

term for many specific illegal activities in the loan industry. <strong>Predatory</strong> lending should<br />

not be confused with predatory mortgage servicing which is mortgage practices<br />

described by critics as unfair, deceptive, or fraudulent practices during the loan or<br />

mortgage servicing process, post loan origination.<br />

One less contentious definition of the term is proposed by an investing website as "the<br />

practice of a lender deceptively convincing borrowers to agree to unfair and abusive<br />

loan terms, or systematically violating those terms in ways that make it difficult for the<br />

borrower to defend against". Other types of lending sometimes also referred to as<br />

predatory include payday loans, certain types of credit cards, mainly subprime, or other<br />

forms of (again, often subprime) consumer debt, and overdraft loans, when the interest<br />

rates are considered unreasonably high. Although predatory lenders are most likely to<br />

target the less educated, the poor, racial minorities, and the elderly, victims of predatory<br />

lending are represented across all demographics.<br />

Page 17 of 181


<strong>Predatory</strong> lending typically occurs on loans backed by some kind of collateral, such as a<br />

car or house, so that if the borrower defaults on the loan, the lender can repossess or<br />

foreclose and profit by selling the repossessed or foreclosed property. Lenders may be<br />

accused of tricking a borrower into believing that an interest rate is lower than it actually<br />

is, or that the borrower's ability to pay is greater than it actually is. The lender, or others<br />

as agents of the lender, may well profit from repossession or foreclosure upon the<br />

collateral.<br />

Abusive or Unfair <strong>Lending</strong> Practices<br />

There are many lending practices which have been called abusive and labeled with the<br />

term "predatory lending". There is a great deal of dispute between lenders and<br />

consumer groups as to what exactly constitutes "unfair" or "predatory" practices, but the<br />

following are sometimes cited:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Unjustified Risk-Based Pricing. This is the practice of charging more (in the<br />

form of higher interest rates and fees) for extending credit to borrowers identified<br />

by the lender as posing a greater credit risk. The lending industry argues that<br />

risk-based pricing is a legitimate practice; since a greater percentage of loans<br />

made to less creditworthy borrowers can be expected to go into default, higher<br />

prices are necessary to obtain the same yield on the portfolio as a whole. Some<br />

consumer groups argue that higher prices paid by more vulnerable consumers<br />

cannot always be justified by increased credit risk.<br />

Single-Premium Credit Insurance. This is the purchase of insurance which will<br />

pay off the loan in case the homebuyer dies. It is more expensive than other<br />

forms of insurance because it does not involve any medical checkups, but<br />

customers almost always are not shown their choices, because usually the<br />

lender is not licensed to sell other forms of insurance. In addition, this insurance<br />

is usually financed into the loan which causes the loan to be more expensive, but<br />

at the same time encourages people to buy the insurance because they do not<br />

have to pay up front.<br />

Failure to Present The Loan Price as Negotiable. Many lenders will negotiate<br />

the price structure of the loan with borrowers. In some situations, borrowers can<br />

even negotiate an outright reduction in the interest rate or other charges on the<br />

loan. Consumer advocates argue that borrowers, especially unsophisticated<br />

borrowers, are not aware of their ability to negotiate and might even be under the<br />

mistaken impression that the lender is placing the borrower's interests above its<br />

own. Thus, many borrowers do not take advantage of their ability to negotiate.<br />

Failure to Clearly and Accurately Disclose Terms and Conditions,<br />

particularly in cases where an unsophisticated borrower is involved. Mortgage<br />

loans are complex transactions involving multiple parties and dozens of pages of<br />

legal documents. In the most egregious of predatory cases, lenders or brokers<br />

Page 18 of 181


have not only misled borrowers but have also altered documents after they have<br />

been signed.<br />

<br />

Short-Term Loans with Disproportionally High Fees, such as payday loans,<br />

credit card late fees, checking account overdraft fees, and Tax Refund<br />

Anticipation Loans, where the fee paid for advancing the money for a short<br />

period of time works out to an annual interest rate significantly in excess of the<br />

market rate for high-risk loans. The originators of such loans dispute that the fees<br />

are interest.<br />

<br />

Servicing Agent and Securitization Abuses. The mortgage servicing agent is<br />

the entity that receives the mortgage payment, maintains the payment records,<br />

provides borrowers with account statements, imposes late charges when the<br />

payment is late, and pursues delinquent borrowers. A securitization is a financial<br />

transaction in which assets, especially debt instruments, are pooled and<br />

securities representing interests in the pool are issued. Most loans are subject to<br />

being bundled and sold, and the rights to act as servicing agent sold, without the<br />

consent of the borrower. A federal statute requires notice to the borrower of a<br />

change in servicing agent, but does not protect the borrower from being held<br />

delinquent on the note for payments made to the servicing agent who fails to<br />

forward the payments to the owner of the note, especially if that servicing agent<br />

goes bankrupt, and borrowers who have made all payments on time can find<br />

Page 19 of 181


themselves being foreclosed on and becoming unsecured creditors of the<br />

servicing agent. Foreclosures can sometimes be conducted without proper notice<br />

to the borrower. In some states (see Texas Rule of Civil Procedure 746), there is<br />

no defense against eviction, forcing the borrower to move and incur the expense<br />

of hiring a lawyer and finding another place to live while litigating the claim of the<br />

"new owner" to own the house, especially after it is resold one or more times.<br />

<br />

When the debtor demands, under the best evidence rule, that the current claimed<br />

note owner produce the original note with the debtor's signature on it, the note<br />

owner typically is unable or unwilling to do so, and tries to establish his claim with<br />

an affidavit that it is the owner, without proving it is the "holder in due course", the<br />

traditional standard for a debt claim, and the courts often allow them to do that. In<br />

the meantime, the note continues to be traded, its physical whereabouts difficult<br />

to discover.<br />

OCC Advisory Letter AL 2003-2 describes predatory lending as including the following:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Loan "flipping" – frequent refinancings that result in little or no economic benefit<br />

to the borrower and are undertaken with the primary or sole objective of<br />

generating additional loan fees, prepayment penalties, and fees from the<br />

financing of credit-related products;<br />

Refinancings of special subsidized mortgages that result in the loss of beneficial<br />

loan terms;<br />

"Packing" of excessive and sometimes "hidden" fees in the amount financed;<br />

Using loan terms or structures – such as negative amortization – to make it more<br />

difficult or impossible for borrowers to reduce or repay their indebtedness;<br />

Using balloon payments to conceal the true burden of the financing and to force<br />

borrowers into costly refinancing transactions or foreclosures;<br />

Targeting inappropriate or excessively expensive credit products to older<br />

borrowers, to persons who are not financially sophisticated or who may be<br />

otherwise vulnerable to abusive practices, and to persons who could qualify for<br />

mainstream credit products and terms;<br />

Inadequate disclosure of the true costs, risks and, where necessary,<br />

appropriateness to the borrower of loan transactions;<br />

The offering of single premium credit life insurance; and<br />

The use of mandatory arbitration clauses.<br />

Page 20 of 181


<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> Towards Minority Groups<br />

Many minority communities have been excluded from loans in the past, they are and<br />

have been more vulnerable to deception. Oftentimes, they are targeted because of<br />

these vulnerabilities. Organizations and agencies including ACORN, HUD, the<br />

American Civil Liberties Union, United for a Fair Economy and more prove that<br />

predatory loans are disproportionately made in poor and minority neighborhoods.<br />

Brokers and lenders preyed on these neighborhoods with the knowledge that these<br />

people were often denied for loans and the demand for loans were high. Lenders called<br />

these neighborhoods never-never land. This created the subprime predatory lending<br />

world.<br />

Subprime lenders specialize in B, C, and D paper. <strong>Predatory</strong> lending is the practice of<br />

overcharging a borrower for rates and fees, average fee should be 1%, these lenders<br />

were charging borrowers over 5%.<br />

Consumers without challenged credit loans should be underwritten with prime lenders.<br />

In 2004 69% of borrowers were from subprime lending. The 2007 mortgage drop and<br />

economy fail were from over lending.<br />

Page 21 of 181


Organizations such as AARP, Inner City Press, and ACORN have worked to stop what<br />

they describe as predatory lending. ACORN has targeted specific companies such as<br />

HSBC Finance, successfully forcing them to change their practices.<br />

Some subprime lending practices have raised concerns about mortgage discrimination<br />

on the basis of race. African Americans and other minorities are being<br />

disproportionately led to sub-prime mortgages with higher interest rates than their white<br />

counterparts. Even when median income levels were comparable, home buyers in<br />

minority neighborhoods were more likely to get a loan from a subprime lender, though<br />

not necessarily a sub-prime loan.<br />

Other Targeted Groups<br />

In addition, studies by leading consumer groups have concluded that women have<br />

become a key component to the subprime mortgage crunch. Professor Anita F. Hill<br />

wrote that a large percentage of first-time home buyers were women, and that loan<br />

officers took advantage of the lack of financial knowledge of many female loan<br />

applicants. Consumers believe that they are protected by consumer protection laws,<br />

when their lender is really operating wholly outside the laws. Refer to 15 U.S.C. 1601<br />

and 12 C.F.R. 226.<br />

Media investigations have disclosed that mortgage lenders used bait-and-switch<br />

salesmanship and fraud to take advantage of borrowers during the home-loan boom. In<br />

February 2005, for example, reporters Michael Hudson and Scott Reckard broke a story<br />

in the Los Angeles Times about "boiler room" sales tactics at Ameriquest Mortgage, the<br />

nation’s largest subprime lender.<br />

Hudson and Reckard cited interviews and court statements by 32 former Ameriquest<br />

employees who said the company had abused its customers and broken the law,<br />

"deceiving borrowers about the terms of their loans, forging documents, falsifying<br />

appraisals and fabricating borrowers' income to qualify them for loans they couldn't<br />

afford". Ameriquest later agreed to pay a $325 million predatory lending settlement with<br />

state authorities across the nation.<br />

Disputes over predatory lending<br />

Some subprime lending advocates, such as the National Home Equity Mortgage<br />

Association (NHEMA), say many practices commonly called "predatory," particularly the<br />

practice of risk-based pricing, are not actually predatory, and that many laws aimed at<br />

reducing "predatory lending" significantly restrict the availability of mortgage finance to<br />

lower-income borrowers. Such parties consider predatory lending a pejorative term.<br />

Page 22 of 181


Underlying Issues<br />

There are many underlying issues in the predatory lending debate:<br />

<br />

Judicial Practices: Some argue that much of the problem arises from a<br />

tendency of the courts to favor lenders, and to shift the burden of proof of<br />

compliance with the terms of the debt instrument to the debtor. According to this<br />

argument, it should not be the duty of the borrower to make sure his payments<br />

are getting to the current note-owner, but to make evidence that all payments<br />

were made to the last known agent for collection sufficient to block or reverse<br />

repossession or foreclosure, and eviction, and to cancel the debt if the current<br />

note owner cannot prove he is the "holder in due course" by producing the actual<br />

original debt instrument in court.<br />

<br />

Risk-Based Pricing: The basic idea is that borrowers who are thought of as<br />

more likely to default on their loans should pay higher interest rates and finance<br />

charges to compensate lenders for the increased risk. In essence, high returns<br />

motivate lenders to lend to a group they might not otherwise lend to – "subprime"<br />

or risky borrowers. Advocates of this system believe that it would be unfair – or a<br />

poor business strategy – to raise interest rates globally to accommodate risky<br />

borrowers, thus penalizing low-risk borrowers who are unlikely to default.<br />

Opponents argue that the practice tends to disproportionately create capital<br />

gains for the affluent while oppressing working-class borrowers with modest<br />

Page 23 of 181


financial resources. Some people consider risk-based pricing to be unfair in<br />

principle. Lenders contend that interest rates are generally set fairly considering<br />

the risk that the lender assumes, and that competition between lenders will<br />

ensure availability of appropriately-priced loans to high-risk customers. Still<br />

others feel that while the rates themselves may be justifiable with respect to the<br />

risks, it is irresponsible for lenders to encourage or allow borrowers with credit<br />

problems to take out high-priced loans. For all of its pros and cons, risk-based<br />

pricing remains a universal practice in bond markets and the insurance industry,<br />

and it is implied in the stock market and in many other open-market venues; it is<br />

only controversial in the case of consumer loans.<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Competition: Some believe that risk-based pricing is fair but feel that many<br />

loans charge prices far above the risk, using the risk as an excuse to overcharge.<br />

These criticisms are not levied on all products, but only on those specifically<br />

deemed predatory. Proponents counter that competition among lenders should<br />

prevent or reduce overcharging.<br />

Financial Education: Many observers feel that competition in the markets<br />

served by what critics describe as "predatory lenders" is not affected by price<br />

because the targeted consumers are completely uneducated about the time<br />

value of money and the concept of Annual percentage rate, a different measure<br />

of price than what many are used to. Recent research looked at a legislative<br />

experiment in which the State of Illinois, which required “high-risk” mortgage<br />

applicants acquiring or refinancing properties in 10 specific zip codes to submit<br />

loan offers from state-licensed lenders to review by HUD-certified financial<br />

counselors. The experiment found that the legislation pushed some borrowers to<br />

choose less risky loan products in order to avoid counseling.<br />

Caveat Emptor: There is an underlying debate about whether a lender should be<br />

allowed to charge whatever it wants for a service, even if there is no evidence<br />

that it attempted to deceive the consumer about the price. At issue here is the<br />

belief that lending is a commodity and that the lending community has an almost<br />

fiduciary duty to advise the borrower that funds can be obtained more cheaply.<br />

Also at issue are certain financial products which appear to be profitable only due<br />

to adverse selection or a lack of knowledge on the part of the customers relative<br />

to the lenders. For example, some people allege that credit insurance would not<br />

be profitable to lending companies if only those customers who had the right "fit"<br />

for the product actually bought it (i.e., only those customers who were not able to<br />

get the generally cheaper term life insurance). Regardless, the majority of U.S.<br />

courts have refused to treat the lender-borrower relationship as a fiduciary one<br />

and declined to impose a duty of care upon lenders in the making of loans. Thus,<br />

once the lender has complied with all relevant statutory disclosure obligations, it<br />

remains solely the borrower's problem to ascertain whether the loan they are<br />

getting is the right fit for them.<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> Borrowing<br />

Page 24 of 181


In an article in the January 17, 2008 New York Times, George Mason University economics<br />

professor Tyler Cowen described "predatory borrowing" as potentially a larger problem than<br />

predatory lending:<br />

"As much as 70 percent of recent early payment defaults had fraudulent<br />

misrepresentations on their original loan applications, according to one recent study.<br />

The research was done by BasePoint Analytics, which helps banks and lenders identify<br />

fraudulent transactions; the study looked at more than three million loans from 1997 to<br />

2006, with a majority from 2005 to 2006. Applications with misrepresentations were also<br />

five times as likely to go into default. Many of the frauds were simple rather than<br />

ingenious. In some cases, borrowers who were asked to state their incomes just lied,<br />

sometimes reporting five times actual income; other borrowers falsified income<br />

documents by using computers."<br />

It should be noted that mortgage applications are usually completed by mortgage<br />

brokers or lenders' in-house loan officers, rather than by borrowers themselves, making<br />

it difficult for borrowers to control the information that was submitted with their<br />

applications.<br />

A stated income loan application is done by the borrower, and no proof of income is<br />

needed. When the broker files the loan, they have to go by whatever income is stated.<br />

This opened the doors for borrowers to be approved for loans that they otherwise would<br />

not qualify for, or afford. However, lawsuits and testimony from former industry insiders<br />

Page 25 of 181


indicated that mortgage company employees frequently were behind overstatements of<br />

borrower income on mortgage applications.<br />

Borrowers had little or no ability to manipulate other key data points that were frequently<br />

falsified during the mortgage process. These included credit scores, home appraisals<br />

and loan-to-value ratios. These were all factors that were under the control of mortgage<br />

professionals. In 2012, for example, New York Attorney General Eric Schneiderman<br />

reached a $7.8 million settlement of allegations that a leading appraisal management<br />

firm had helped inflate real estate appraisals on a wide scale basis in order to help a<br />

major lender push through more loan deals. The attorney general office's lawsuit<br />

alleged that eAppraiseIT, which did more than 260,000 appraisals nationally for<br />

Washington Mutual, caved to pressure from WaMu loan officers to select pliable<br />

appraisers who were willing to submit inflated property valuations.<br />

Several commentators have dismissed the notion of "predatory borrowing", accusing<br />

those making this argument as being apologists for the lack of lending standards and<br />

other excesses during the credit bubble.<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> servicing is also a component of predatory lending, characterized by unfair,<br />

deceptive, or fraudulent practices by a lender or another company that services a loan<br />

on behalf of the lender, after the loan is granted. Those practices include also charging<br />

excessive and unsubstantiated fees and expenses for servicing the loan, wrongfully<br />

disclosing credit defaults by a borrower, harassing a borrower for repayment and<br />

refusing to act in good faith in working with a borrower to effectuate a mortgage<br />

modification as required by federal law.<br />

Legislation<br />

In many countries, legislation aims to control this, but research has found ambiguous<br />

results, including finding that high-cost mortgage applications can possibly rise after<br />

adoption of laws against predatory lending.<br />

United States<br />

Many laws at both the Federal and state government level are aimed at preventing<br />

predatory lending. Although not specifically anti-predatory in nature, the Federal Truth in<br />

<strong>Lending</strong> Act requires certain disclosures of APR and loan terms. Also, in 1994 section<br />

32 of the Truth in <strong>Lending</strong> Act, entitled the Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act<br />

of 1994, was created. This law is devoted to identifying certain high-cost, potentially<br />

predatory mortgage loans and reining in their terms. Twenty-five states have passed<br />

anti-predatory lending laws. Arkansas, Georgia, Illinois, Maine, Massachusetts, North<br />

Carolina, New York, New Jersey, New Mexico and South Carolina are among those<br />

states considered to have the strongest laws. Other states with predatory lending laws<br />

include: California, Colorado, Connecticut, Florida, Kentucky, Maine, Maryland, Nevada,<br />

Page 26 of 181


Ohio, Oklahoma, Oregon, Pennsylvania, Texas, Utah, Wisconsin, and West Virginia.<br />

These laws usually describe one or more classes of "high-cost" or "covered" loans,<br />

which are defined by the fees charged to the borrower at origination or the APR. While<br />

lenders are not prohibited from making "high-cost" or "covered" loans, a number of<br />

additional restrictions are placed on these loans, and the penalties for noncompliance<br />

can be substantial.<br />

________<br />

Subprime <strong>Lending</strong><br />

In finance, subprime lending (also referred to as near-prime, subpar, non-prime, and<br />

second-chance lending) means making loans to people who may have difficulty<br />

maintaining the repayment schedule,<br />

sometimes reflecting setbacks, such<br />

as unemployment, divorce, medical<br />

emergencies, etc. Historically,<br />

subprime borrowers were defined as<br />

having FICO scores below 600,<br />

although "this has varied over time<br />

and circumstances."<br />

These loans are characterized by<br />

higher interest rates, poor quality<br />

collateral, and less favorable terms<br />

in order to compensate for higher<br />

credit risk. Many subprime loans<br />

were packaged into mortgagebacked<br />

securities (MBS) and<br />

ultimately defaulted, contributing to<br />

the financial crisis of 2007–2008.<br />

Proponents of subprime lending maintain that the practice extends credit to people who<br />

would otherwise not have access to the credit market. Professor Harvey S. Rosen of<br />

Princeton University explained, "The main thing that innovations in the mortgage market<br />

have done over the past 30 years is to let in the excluded: the young, the discriminated<br />

against, the people without a lot of money in the bank to use for a down payment."<br />

Defining Subprime Risk<br />

The term subprime refers to the credit quality of particular borrowers, who have<br />

weakened credit histories and a greater risk of loan default than prime borrowers. As<br />

people become economically active, records are created relating to their borrowing,<br />

earning and lending history. This is called a credit rating; although covered by privacy<br />

laws, the information is readily available to people with a need to know (in some<br />

countries, loan applications specifically allow the lender to access such records).<br />

Page 27 of 181


Subprime borrowers have credit ratings that might include:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

limited debt experience (so the lender's assessor simply does not know, and<br />

assumes the worst), or<br />

no possession of property assets that could be used as security (for the lender to<br />

sell in case of default)<br />

excessive debt (the known income of the individual or family is unlikely to be<br />

enough to pay living expenses + interest + repayment),<br />

a history of late or sometimes missed payments so that the loan period had to be<br />

extended,<br />

failures to pay debts completely (default debt), and<br />

any legal judgments such as "orders to pay" or bankruptcy (sometimes known in<br />

Britain as county court judgments or CCJs).<br />

Lenders' standards for determining risk categories may also consider the size of the<br />

proposed loan, and also take into account the way the loan and the repayment plan is<br />

structured, if it is a conventional repayment loan, a mortgage loan, an endowment<br />

mortgage, an interest-only loan, a standard repayment loan, an amortized loan, a credit<br />

card limit or some other arrangement. The originator is also taken into consideration.<br />

Because of this, it was possible for a loan to a borrower with "prime" characteristics<br />

(e.g. high credit score, low debt) to be classified as subprime.<br />

Student Loans<br />

In the United States the amount of student loan debt recently surpassed credit card<br />

debt, hitting the $1 trillion mark in 2012. However, that $1 trillion rapidly grew by 50% to<br />

$1.5 trillion as of 2018. In other countries such loans are underwritten by governments<br />

or sponsors. Many student loans are structured in special ways because of the difficulty<br />

of predicting students' future earnings.<br />

These structures may be in the form of soft loans, income-sensitive repayment loans,<br />

income-contingent repayment loans and so on. Because student loans provide<br />

repayment records for credit rating, and may also indicate their earning potential,<br />

student loan default can cause serious problems later in life as an individual wishes to<br />

make a substantial purchase on credit such as purchasing a vehicle or buying a house,<br />

since defaulters are likely to be classified as subprime, which means the loan may be<br />

refused or more difficult to arrange and certainly more expensive than for someone with<br />

a perfect repayment record.<br />

Page 28 of 181


United States<br />

Although there is no single, standard definition, in the United States subprime loans are<br />

usually classified as those where the borrower has a FICO score below 640. The term<br />

was popularized by the media during the subprime mortgage crisis or "credit crunch" of<br />

2007. Those loans which do not meet Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac underwriting<br />

guidelines for prime mortgages are called "non-conforming" loans. As such, they cannot<br />

be packaged into Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac MBS.<br />

A borrower with an outstanding record of repayment on time and in full will get what is<br />

called an A-paper loan. Borrowers with less-than-perfect credit 'scores' might be rated<br />

as meriting an A-minus, B-paper, C-paper or D-paper loan, with interest payments<br />

progressively increased for less reliable payers to allow the company to 'share the risk'<br />

of default equitably among all its borrowers. Between A-paper and subprime in risk is<br />

Alt-A.<br />

A-minus is related to Alt-A, with some lenders categorizing them the same, but A-minus<br />

is traditionally defined as mortgage borrowers with a FICO score of below 680 while Alt-<br />

A is traditionally defined as loans lacking full documentation. The value of U.S.<br />

subprime mortgages was estimated at $1.3 trillion as of March 2007, with over<br />

7.5 million first-lien subprime mortgages outstanding.<br />

Page 29 of 181


Canada<br />

The sub-prime market did not take hold in Canada to the extent that it did in the U.S.,<br />

where the vast majority of mortgages were originated by third parties and then<br />

packaged and sold to investors who often did not understand the associated risk.<br />

Subprime Crisis<br />

The subprime mortgage crisis arose from 'bundling' American subprime and American<br />

regular mortgages into MBSs that were traditionally isolated from, and sold in a<br />

separate market from, prime loans. These 'bundles' of mixed (prime and subprime)<br />

mortgages were based on asset-backed securities so the 'probable' rate of return<br />

looked superb (since subprime lenders pay higher premiums on loans secured against<br />

saleable real-estate, which was commonly assumed "could not fail"). Many subprime<br />

mortgages had a low initial interest rate for the first two or three years and those who<br />

defaulted were 'swapped' regularly at first, but finally, a bigger share of borrowers began<br />

to default in staggering numbers. The inflated house-price bubble burst, property<br />

valuations plummeted and the real rate of return on investment could not be estimated,<br />

and so confidence in these instruments collapsed, and all less than prime mortgages<br />

were considered to be almost worthless toxic assets, regardless of their actual<br />

composition or performance. Because of the "originate-to-distribute" model followed by<br />

many subprime mortgage originators, there was little monitoring of credit quality and<br />

little effort at remediation when these mortgages became troubled.<br />

To avoid high initial mortgage payments, many subprime borrowers took out adjustablerate<br />

mortgages (or ARMs) that give them a lower initial interest rate. But with potential<br />

annual adjustments of 2% or more per year, these loans can end up costing much<br />

more. So a $500,000 loan at a 4% interest rate for 30 years equates to a payment of<br />

about $2,400 a month. But the same loan at 10% for 27 years (after the adjustable<br />

period ends) equates to a payment of $4,220. A 6-percentage-point increase (from 4%<br />

to 10%) in the rate caused slightly more than a 75% increase in the payment. This is<br />

even more apparent when the lifetime cost of the loan is considered (though most<br />

people will want to refinance their loans periodically). The total cost of the above loan at<br />

4% is $864,000, while the higher rate of 10% would incur a lifetime cost of $1,367,280.<br />

Page 30 of 181


II. The Poverty Industry, Economic<br />

Inequality, and Redlining<br />

The Poverty Industry<br />

The terms Poverty Industry or Poverty Business refer to a wide range of<br />

money-making activities that attract a large portion of their business from the poor<br />

because they are poor. Businesses in the poverty industry often include payday loan<br />

centers, pawnshops, rent-to-own centers, casinos, liquor stores, lotteries, tobacco<br />

stores, credit card companies, and bail-bond services. Illegal ventures such as<br />

loansharking might also be included. The poverty industry makes roughly US$33 billion<br />

a year in the United States. In 2010, elected American federal officials received more<br />

than $1.5 million in campaign contributions from poverty-industry donors.<br />

Income Inequality<br />

Economic Inequality is the difference found in various measures of economic wellbeing<br />

among individuals in a group, among groups in a population, or among countries.<br />

Page 31 of 181


Economic inequality sometimes refers to income inequality, wealth inequality, or the<br />

wealth gap. Economists generally focus on economic disparity in three metrics: wealth,<br />

income, and consumption. The issue of economic inequality is relevant to notions of<br />

equity, equality of outcome, and equality of opportunity.<br />

Economic inequality varies between societies, historical periods, economic structures<br />

and systems. The term can refer to cross-sectional distribution of income or wealth at<br />

any particular period, or to changes of income and wealth over longer periods of time.<br />

There are various numerical indices for measuring economic inequality. A widely used<br />

index is the Gini coefficient, but there are also many other methods.<br />

Research suggests that greater inequality hinders the duration of growth but not its rate.<br />

Whereas globalization has reduced global inequality (between nations), it has increased<br />

inequality within nations.<br />

Empirical Measurements of Inequality<br />

The first set of income distribution statistics for the United States covering the period<br />

from (1913–48) was published in 1952 by Simon Kuznets, Shares of Upper Income<br />

Groups in Income and Savings. It relied on US federal income tax returns and Kuznets's<br />

own estimates of US national income, National Income: A Summary of Findings (1946).<br />

Others who contributed to development of accurate income distribution statistics during<br />

the early 20th century were John Whitefield Kendrick in the United States, Arthur<br />

Bowley and Colin Clark in the UK, and L. Dugé de Bernonville in France.<br />

Economists generally consider three metrics of economic dispersion: wealth, income,<br />

and consumption. A skilled professional may have low wealth and low income as<br />

student, low wealth and high earnings in the beginning of the career, and high wealth<br />

and low earnings after the career. People's preferences determine whether they<br />

consume earnings immediately or defer consumption to the future. The distinction is<br />

also important at the level of economy:<br />

<br />

<br />

There are economies with high income inequality and relatively low wealth<br />

inequality (such as Japan and Italy).<br />

There are economies with relatively low income inequality and high wealth<br />

inequality (such as Switzerland and Denmark).<br />

There are different ways to measure income inequality and wealth inequality. Different<br />

choices lead to different results. The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and<br />

Development (OECD) provides data on the following eight types of income inequality:<br />

<br />

<br />

Dispersion of hourly wages among full-time (or full-time equivalent) workers<br />

Wage dispersion among workers – E.g. annual wages, including wages from<br />

part-time work or work during only part of the year.<br />

Page 32 of 181


Individual earnings inequality among all workers – Includes the self-employed.<br />

Individual earnings inequality among the entire working-age population –<br />

Includes those who are inactive, e.g. students, unemployed, early pensioners,<br />

etc.<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Household earnings inequality – Includes the earnings of all household<br />

members.<br />

Household market income inequality – Includes incomes from capital, savings<br />

and private transfers.<br />

Household disposable income inequality – Includes public cash transfers<br />

received and direct taxes paid.<br />

Household adjusted disposable income inequality – Includes publicly provided<br />

services.<br />

There are many challenges in comparing data between economies, or in a single<br />

economy in different years. Examples of challenges include:<br />

Page 33 of 181


Data can be based on joint taxation of couples (e.g. France, Germany, Ireland,<br />

Netherlands, Portugal and Switzerland) or individual taxation (e.g. Australia,<br />

Canada, Italy, Japan, New Zealand, Spain, the UK).<br />

The tax authorities generally only collect information on income that is potentially<br />

taxable.<br />

The precise definition of gross income varies from country to country. There are<br />

differences when it comes to inclusion of pension entitlements and other savings,<br />

and benefits such as employer provided health insurance.<br />

Differences when it comes under-declaration of income and/or wealth in tax<br />

filings.<br />

A special event like an exit from business may lead to a very high income in one<br />

year, but much lower income in other years of the person's lifetime.<br />

Much income and wealth in non-western countries is obtained or held extralegally<br />

through black market and underground activities such as unregistered<br />

businesses, informal property ownership arrangements, etc.<br />

Measurements<br />

Share of income of the top 1% for<br />

selected developed countries, 1975<br />

to 2015<br />

it concluded that following factors had a role:<br />

In 1820, the ratio between<br />

the income of the top and<br />

bottom 20 percent of the<br />

world's population was three<br />

to one. By 1991, it was<br />

eighty-six to one. A 2011<br />

study titled "Divided we<br />

Stand: Why Inequality Keeps<br />

Rising" by the Organisation<br />

for Economic Co-operation<br />

and Development (OECD)<br />

sought to explain the causes<br />

for this rising inequality by<br />

investigating economic<br />

inequality in OECD countries;<br />

Page 34 of 181


Changes in the structure of households can play an important role. Singleheaded<br />

households in OECD countries have risen from an average of 15% in the<br />

late 1980s to 20% in the mid-2000s, resulting in higher inequality.<br />

Assortative mating refers to the phenomenon of people marrying people with<br />

similar background, for example doctors marrying doctors rather than nurses.<br />

OECD found out that 40% of couples where both partners work belonged to the<br />

same or neighboring earnings deciles compared with 33% some 20 years before.<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

In the bottom percentiles number of hours worked has decreased.<br />

The main reason for increasing inequality seems to be the difference between<br />

the demand for and supply of skills.<br />

Income inequality in OECD countries is at its highest level for the past half<br />

century. The ratio between the bottom 10% and the top 10% has increased from<br />

1:7, to 1:9 in 25 years.<br />

There are tentative signs of a possible convergence of inequality levels towards a<br />

common and higher average level across OECD countries.<br />

Page 35 of 181


With very few exceptions (France, Japan, and Spain), the wages of the 10%<br />

best-paid workers have risen relative to those of the 10% lowest paid.<br />

A 2011 OECD study investigated economic inequality in Argentina, Brazil, China, India,<br />

Indonesia, Russia and South Africa. It concluded that key sources of inequality in these<br />

countries include "a large, persistent informal sector, widespread regional divides (e.g.<br />

urban-rural), gaps in access to education, and barriers to employment and career<br />

progression for women."<br />

A study by the World Institute for Development Economics Research at United Nations<br />

University reports that the richest 1% of adults alone owned 40% of global assets in the<br />

year 2000. The three richest people in the world possess more financial assets than the<br />

lowest 48 nations combined. The combined wealth of the "10 million dollar millionaires"<br />

grew to nearly $41 trillion in 2008. A January 2014 report by Oxfam claims that the 85<br />

wealthiest individuals in the world have a combined wealth equal to that of the bottom<br />

50% of the world's population, or about 3.5 billion people. According to a Los Angeles<br />

Times analysis of the report, the wealthiest 1% owns 46% of the world's wealth; the 85<br />

richest people, a small part of the wealthiest 1%, own about 0.7% of the human<br />

population's wealth, which is the same as the bottom half of the population. In January<br />

2015, Oxfam reported that the wealthiest 1 percent will own more than half of the global<br />

wealth by 2016. An October 2014 study by Credit Suisse also claims that the top 1%<br />

now own nearly half of the world's wealth and that the accelerating disparity could<br />

trigger a recession.<br />

In October 2015, Credit Suisse published a study which shows global inequality<br />

continues to increase, and that half of the world's wealth is now in the hands of those in<br />

the top percentile, whose assets each exceed $759,900. A 2016 report by Oxfam claims<br />

that the 62 wealthiest individuals own as much wealth as the poorer half of the global<br />

population combined. Oxfam's claims have however been questioned on the basis of<br />

the methodology used: by using net wealth (adding up assets and subtracting debts),<br />

the Oxfam report, for instance, finds that there are more poor people in the United<br />

States and Western Europe than in China (due to a greater tendency to take on debts).<br />

Anthony Shorrocks, the lead author of the Credit Suisse report which is one of the<br />

sources of Oxfam's data, considers the criticism about debt to be a "silly argument" and<br />

"a non-issue . . . a diversion." Oxfam's 2017 report says the top eight billionaires have<br />

as much wealth as the bottom half of the global population, and that rising inequality is<br />

suppressing wages, as businesses are focused on delivering higher returns to wealthy<br />

owners and executives. In 2018, the Oxfam report said that the wealth gap continued to<br />

widen in 2017, with 82% of global wealth generated going to the wealthiest 1%.<br />

According to PolitiFact the top 400 richest Americans "have more wealth than half of all<br />

Americans combined." According to The New York Times on July 22, 2014, the "richest<br />

1 percent in the United States now own more wealth than the bottom 90 percent".<br />

Inherited wealth may help explain why many Americans who have become rich may<br />

have had a "substantial head start". In September 2012, according to the Institute for<br />

Policy Studies (IPS), "over 60 percent" of the Forbes richest 400 Americans "grew up in<br />

Page 36 of 181


substantial privilege". A 2017 report by the IPS said that three individuals, Jeff Bezos,<br />

Bill Gates and Warren Buffett, own as much wealth as the bottom half of the population,<br />

or 160 million people, and that the growing disparity between the wealthy and the poor<br />

has created a "moral crisis", noting that "we have not witnessed such extreme levels of<br />

concentrated wealth and power since the first gilded age a century ago." In 2016, the<br />

world's billionaires increased their combined global wealth to a record $6 trillion.<br />

The existing data and estimates suggest a large increase in international (and more<br />

generally inter-macro-regional) component between 1820 and 1960. It might have<br />

slightly decreased since that time at the expense of increasing inequality within<br />

countries.<br />

The United Nations Development Program in 2014 asserted that greater investments in<br />

social security, jobs and laws that protect vulnerable populations are necessary to<br />

prevent widening income inequality ... .<br />

There is a significant difference in the measured wealth distribution and the public's<br />

understanding of wealth distribution. Michael Norton of the Harvard Business School<br />

and Dan Ariely of the Department of Psychology at Duke University found this to be true<br />

in their research, done in 2011. The actual wealth going to the top quintile in 2011 was<br />

around 84% where as the average amount of wealth that the general public estimated<br />

to go to the top quintile was around 58%.<br />

Page 37 of 181


Two researchers claim that global income inequality is decreasing, due to strong<br />

economic growth in developing countries. However, the OECD reported in 2015 that<br />

income inequality is higher than it has ever been within OECD member nations and is at<br />

increased levels in many emerging economies. According to a June 2015 report by the<br />

International Monetary Fund:<br />

Widening income inequality is the defining challenge of our time. In advanced<br />

economies, the gap between the rich and poor is at its highest level in decades.<br />

Inequality trends have been more mixed in emerging markets and developing countries<br />

(EMDCs), with some countries experiencing declining inequality, but pervasive<br />

inequities in access to education, health care, and finance remain.<br />

In October 2017, the IMF warned that inequality within nations, in spite of global<br />

inequality falling in recent decades, has risen so sharply that it threatens economic<br />

growth and could result in further political polarization. The Fund's Fiscal Monitor report<br />

said that "progressive taxation and transfers are key components of efficient fiscal<br />

redistribution."<br />

Wealth Distribution within Individual Countries<br />

The following table shows information about wealth distribution in different countries,<br />

from a 2013 report by Crédit Suisse. Wealth can be negative for people who are in debt,<br />

and if there are enough people in debt in a country, the Gini coefficient can be greater<br />

than 100%, as seen in the case of Denmark. The Gini coefficients for wealth are often<br />

much higher than those for income. This is the case for example in Scandinavian<br />

countries such as Sweden and Finland. For example, in Sweden about 24% of<br />

households have negative wealth (or zero). This seems to be due to factors such as<br />

social insurance programmes (welfare) and the public pension scheme. [49]<br />

Global Wealth Distribution - Wealth<br />

patterns within countries.<br />

From information provided by the<br />

Credit Suisse, Research Institute's<br />

"Global Wealth Databook", published<br />

2013.<br />

Countries' income inequality according to<br />

their most recent reported Gini index values<br />

(often 10+ years old) as of 2014:<br />

red = high, green = low inequality<br />

Income Distribution within Individual Countries<br />

A Gini index value above 50 is considered high; countries including Brazil, Colombia,<br />

South Africa, Botswana, and Honduras can be found in this category. A Gini index value<br />

Page 38 of 181


of 30 or above is considered medium; countries including Vietnam, Mexico, Poland, The<br />

United States, Argentina, Russia and Uruguay can be found in this category. A Gini<br />

index value lower than 30 is considered low; countries including Austria, Germany,<br />

Denmark, Slovenia, Sweden and Ukraine can be found in this category.<br />

Causes<br />

There are various reasons for economic inequality within societies. Recent growth in<br />

overall income inequality, at least within the OECD countries, has been driven mostly by<br />

increasing inequality in wages and salaries.<br />

Economist Thomas Piketty argues that widening economic disparity is an inevitable<br />

phenomenon of free market capitalism when the rate of return of capital (r) is greater<br />

than the rate of growth of the economy (g).<br />

Common factors thought to impact economic inequality include:<br />

<br />

labor market outcomes<br />

Page 39 of 181


globalization, by:<br />

o<br />

o<br />

o<br />

o<br />

o<br />

suppressing wages in low-skill jobs due to a surplus of low-skill labor in<br />

developing countries<br />

increasing the market size and the rewards for people and firms<br />

succeeding in a particular niche<br />

providing more investment opportunities for already-wealthy people<br />

increasing international influence<br />

decreasing domestic influence<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

policy reforms<br />

extra-legal ownership of property (real estate and business)<br />

more regressive taxation<br />

plutocracy<br />

computerization, automation and increased technology, which means more skills<br />

are required to obtain a moderate or high wage<br />

ethnic discrimination<br />

gender discrimination<br />

nepotism<br />

variation in natural ability<br />

neoliberalism<br />

Growing acceptance of very high CEO salaries, e.g. in the United States since<br />

the 1960s<br />

Land speculation – Followers of Henry George believe that landlords and land<br />

speculators derive excess wealth and income from the tendency of land to<br />

increase exponentially with development and at a much higher rate than<br />

population growth. Their solution is to tax land value, though not necessarily<br />

structures or other improvements. This concept is known as Georgism.<br />

Page 40 of 181


Theoretical Frameworks<br />

Neoclassical Economics<br />

Neoclassical economics views inequalities in the distribution of income as arising from<br />

differences in value added by labor, capital and land. Within labor income distribution is<br />

due to differences in value added by different classifications of workers. In this<br />

perspective, wages and profits are determined by the marginal value added of each<br />

economic actor (worker, capitalist/business owner, landlord). Thus, in a market<br />

economy, inequality is a reflection of the productivity gap between highly-paid<br />

professions and lower-paid professions.<br />

Marxian Economics<br />

Marxian economics attributes rising inequality to job automation and capital deepening<br />

within capitalism. The process of job automation conflicts with the capitalist property<br />

form and its attendant system of wage labor.<br />

In Marxian analysis, capitalist firms increasingly substitute capital equipment for labor<br />

inputs (workers) under competitive pressure to reduce costs and maximize profits. Over<br />

the long-term, this trend increases the organic composition of capital, meaning that less<br />

workers are required in proportion to capital inputs, increasing unemployment (the<br />

Page 41 of 181


"reserve army of labor"). This process exerts a downward pressure on wages. The<br />

substitution of capital equipment for labor (mechanization and automation) raises the<br />

productivity of each worker, resulting in a situation of relatively stagnant wages for the<br />

working class amidst rising levels of property income for the capitalist class.<br />

Labor Market<br />

A major cause of economic inequality within modern market economies is the<br />

determination of wages by the market. Where competition is imperfect; information<br />

unevenly distributed; opportunities to acquire education and skills unequal market<br />

failure results. Since many such imperfect conditions exist in virtually every market,<br />

there is in fact little presumption that markets are in general efficient. This means that<br />

there is an enormous potential role for government to correct such market failures.<br />

In a purely capitalist mode of production (i.e. where professional and labor organizations<br />

cannot limit the number of workers) the workers wages will not be controlled by these<br />

organizations, or by the employer, but rather by the market. Wages work in the same<br />

way as prices for any other good. Thus, wages can be considered as a function of<br />

market price of skill. And therefore, inequality is driven by this price. Under the law of<br />

supply and demand, the price of skill is determined by a race between the demand for<br />

the skilled worker and the supply of the skilled worker. "On the other hand, markets can<br />

also concentrate wealth, pass environmental costs on to society, and abuse workers<br />

and consumers." "Markets, by themselves, even when they are stable, often lead to<br />

high levels of inequality, outcomes that are widely viewed as unfair." Employers who<br />

offer a below market wage will find that their business is chronically understaffed. Their<br />

competitors will take advantage of the situation by offering a higher wage the best of<br />

their labor. For a businessman who has the profit motive as the prime interest, it is a<br />

losing proposition to offer below or above market wages to workers.<br />

A job where there are many workers willing to work a large amount of time (high supply)<br />

competing for a job that few require (low demand) will result in a low wage for that job.<br />

This is because competition between workers drives down the wage. An example of this<br />

would be jobs such as dish-washing or customer service. Competition amongst workers<br />

tends to drive down wages due to the expendable nature of the worker in relation to his<br />

or her particular job. A job where there are few able or willing workers (low supply), but<br />

a large need for the positions (high demand), will result in high wages for that job. This<br />

is because competition between employers for employees will drive up the wage.<br />

Examples of this would include jobs that require highly developed skills, rare abilities, or<br />

a high level of risk. Competition amongst employers tends to drive up wages due to the<br />

nature of the job, since there is a relative shortage of workers for the particular position.<br />

Professional and labor organizations may limit the supply of workers which results in<br />

higher demand and greater incomes for members. Members may also receive higher<br />

wages through collective bargaining, political influence, or corruption.<br />

These supply and demand interactions result in a gradation of wage levels within<br />

society that significantly influence economic inequality. Polarization of wages does not<br />

Page 42 of 181


explain the accumulation of wealth and very high incomes among the 1%. Joseph<br />

Stiglitz believes that "It is plain that markets must be tamed and tempered to make sure<br />

they work to the benefit of most citizens."<br />

On the other hand, higher economic inequality tends to increase entrepreneurship rates<br />

at the individual level (self-employment). However, most of it is often based on<br />

necessity rather than opportunity. Necessity-based entrepreneurship is motivated by<br />

survival needs such as income for food and shelter ("push" motivations), whereas<br />

opportunity-based entrepreneurship is driven by achievement-oriented motivations<br />

("pull") such as vocation and more likely to involve the pursue of new products,<br />

services, or underserved market needs. The economic impact of the former type of<br />

entrepreneurialism tends to be redistributive while the latter is expected to foster<br />

technological progress and thus have a more positive impact on economic growth.<br />

Taxes<br />

Another cause is the rate at which income is taxed coupled with the progressivity of the<br />

tax system. A progressive tax is a tax by which the tax rate increases as the taxable<br />

base amount increases. In a progressive tax system, the level of the top tax rate will<br />

often have a direct impact on the level of inequality within a society, either increasing it<br />

or decreasing it, provided that income does not change as a result of the change in tax<br />

regime. Additionally, steeper tax progressivity applied to social spending can result in a<br />

more equal distribution of income across the board. The difference between the Gini<br />

index for an income distribution before taxation and the Gini index after taxation is an<br />

indicator for the effects of such taxation.<br />

There is debate between politicians and economists over the role of tax policy in<br />

mitigating or exacerbating wealth inequality. Economists such as Paul Krugman, Peter<br />

Orszag, and Emmanuel Saez have argued that tax policy in the post World War II era<br />

Page 43 of 181


has indeed increased income inequality by enabling the wealthiest Americans far<br />

greater access to capital than lower-income ones.<br />

A paper by economists Annette Alstadsæter, Niels Johannesen and Gabriel Zucman,<br />

which used data from HSBC Switzerland ("Swiss leaks") and Mossack Fonseca<br />

("Panama Papers"), found that "on average about 3% of personal taxes are evaded in<br />

Scandinavia, but this figure rises to about 30% in the top 0.01% of the wealth<br />

distribution... Taking tax evasion into account increases the rise in inequality seen in tax<br />

data since the 1970s markedly, highlighting the need to move beyond tax data to<br />

capture income and wealth at the top, even in countries where tax compliance is<br />

generally high. We also find that after reducing tax evasion—by using tax amnesties—<br />

tax evaders do not legally avoid taxes more. This result suggests that fighting tax<br />

evasion can be an effective way to collect more tax revenue from the ultra-wealthy."<br />

In its October 2017 report, the International Monetary Fund argued that increasing taxes<br />

on the top 1% of income earners would reduce economic inequality without hindering<br />

economic growth.<br />

Education<br />

An important factor in the creation of inequality is variation in individuals' access to<br />

education. Education, especially in an area where there is a high demand for workers,<br />

creates high wages for those with this education, however, increases in education first<br />

increase and then decrease growth as well as income inequality. As a result, those who<br />

are unable to afford an education, or choose not to pursue optional education, generally<br />

receive much lower wages. The justification for this is that a lack of education leads<br />

directly to lower incomes, and thus lower aggregate savings and investment.<br />

Conversely, education raises incomes and promotes growth because it helps to unleash<br />

the productive potential of the poor.<br />

In 2014, economists with the Standard & Poor's rating agency concluded that the<br />

widening disparity between the U.S.'s wealthiest citizens and the rest of the nation had<br />

slowed its recovery from the 2008–09 recession and made it more prone to boom-andbust<br />

cycles. To partially remedy the wealth gap and the resulting slow growth, S&P<br />

recommended increasing access to education. It estimated that if the average United<br />

States worker had completed just one more year of school, it would add an additional<br />

$105 billion in growth to the country's economy over five years.<br />

During the mass high school education movement from 1910–40, there was an increase<br />

in skilled workers, which led to a decrease in the price of skilled labor. High school<br />

education during the period was designed to equip students with necessary skill sets to<br />

be able to perform at work. In fact, it differs from the present high school education,<br />

which is regarded as a stepping-stone to acquire college and advanced degrees. This<br />

decrease in wages caused a period of compression and decreased inequality between<br />

skilled and unskilled workers. Education is very important for the growth of the<br />

economy, however educational inequality in gender also influence towards the<br />

Page 44 of 181


economy. Lagerlof and Galor stated that gender inequality in education can result to low<br />

economic growth, and continued gender inequality in education, thus creating a poverty<br />

trap. It is suggested that a large gap in male and female education may indicate<br />

backwardness and so may be associated with lower economic growth, which can<br />

explain why there is economic inequality between countries.<br />

More of Barro studies also find that female secondary education is positively associated<br />

with growth. His findings show that countries with low female education; increasing it<br />

has little effect on economic growth, however in countries with high female education,<br />

increasing it significantly boosts economic growth. More and better education is a<br />

prerequisite for rapid economic development around the world. Education stimulates<br />

economic growth and improves people's lives through many channels.<br />

By increasing the efficiency of the labour force it create better conditions for good<br />

governance, improving health and enhancing equality. Labor market success is linked<br />

to schooling achievement, the consequences of widening disparities in schooling is<br />

likely to be further increases in earnings inequality<br />

The United States funds education through property taxes, which can lead to large<br />

discrepancies in the amount of funding a public school may receive. Often, but not<br />

always, this results in more funding for schools attended by children from wealthier<br />

parents. As of 2015 the United States, Israel, and Turkey are the only three OECD<br />

Page 45 of 181


countries where the government spends more on schools in rich neighborhoods than in<br />

poor neighborhoods.<br />

Economic Liberalism, Deregulation and Decline of Unions<br />

John Schmitt and Ben Zipperer (2006) of the CEPR point to economic liberalism and<br />

the reduction of business regulation along with the decline of union membership as one<br />

of the causes of economic inequality. In an analysis of the effects of intensive Anglo-<br />

American liberal policies in comparison to continental European liberalism, where<br />

unions have remained strong, they concluded "The U.S. economic and social model is<br />

associated with substantial levels of social exclusion, including high levels of income<br />

inequality, high relative and absolute poverty rates, poor and unequal educational<br />

outcomes, poor health outcomes, and high rates of crime and incarceration. At the<br />

same time, the available evidence provides little support for the view that U.S.-style<br />

labor market flexibility dramatically improves labor-market outcomes. Despite popular<br />

prejudices to the contrary, the U.S. economy consistently affords a lower level of<br />

economic mobility than all the continental European countries for which data is<br />

available."<br />

Sociologist Jake Rosenfield of the University of Washington argues that the decline of<br />

organized labor in the United States has played a more significant role in expanding the<br />

income gap than technological changes and globalization, which were also experienced<br />

by other industrialized nations that didn't experience steep surges in inequality. He<br />

points out that nations with high rates of unionization, particularly in Scandinavia, have<br />

very low levels of inequality, and concludes "the historical pattern is clear; the crossnational<br />

pattern is clear: high inequality goes hand-in-hand with weak labor movements<br />

and vice-versa."<br />

A 2015 study by the International Monetary Fund found that the decline of unionization<br />

in many advanced economies starting in the 1980s has fueled rising income inequality.<br />

In 2016, researchers at the IMF concluded that neoliberal policies imposed by economic<br />

elites have exacerbated inequality to such an extent that it is slowing economic growth<br />

and "jeopardizing durable expansion." Their report highlights "three disquieting<br />

conclusions":<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

The benefits in terms of increased growth seem fairly difficult to establish when<br />

looking at a broad group of countries.<br />

The costs in terms of increased inequality are prominent. Such costs epitomize<br />

the trade-off between the growth and equity effects of some aspects of the<br />

neoliberal agenda.<br />

Increased inequality in turn hurts the level and sustainability of growth. Even if<br />

growth is the sole or main purpose of the neoliberal agenda, advocates of that<br />

agenda still need to pay attention to the distributional effects.<br />

Page 46 of 181


On the other hand, Jonathan Rothwell notes that studying the "increase in the income<br />

share of the top 1 percent" in countries in the OECD between 1980 and 2014 finds "no<br />

correlation across countries" between the change in inequality and change in labor's<br />

share of GDP. Both inequality and labor's share of GDP have risen in the UK, while in<br />

the Netherlands labor's share has fallen and inequality is unchanged.<br />

Information Technology<br />

The growth in importance of information technology has been credited with increasing<br />

income inequality. Technology has been called "the main driver of the recent increases<br />

in inequality" by Erik Brynjolfsson, of MIT. In arguing against this explanation, Jonathan<br />

Rothwell notes that if technological advancement is measured by high rates of<br />

invention, there is a negative correlation between it and inequality. Countries with high<br />

invention rates — "as measured by patent applications filed under the Patent<br />

Cooperation Treaty" — exhibit lower inequality than those with less. In one country, the<br />

United States, "salaries of engineers and software developers rarely reach" above<br />

$390,000/year (the lower limit for the top 1% earners).<br />

Globalization<br />

Change in real income between 1988 and 2008<br />

at various income percentiles of global income<br />

distribution.<br />

Trade liberalization may shift<br />

economic inequality from a global to<br />

a domestic scale. When rich<br />

countries trade with poor countries,<br />

the low-skilled workers in the rich<br />

countries may see reduced wages<br />

as a result of the competition, while low-skilled workers in the poor countries may see<br />

increased wages. Trade economist Paul Krugman estimates that trade liberalisation has<br />

had a measurable effect on the rising inequality in the United States. He attributes this<br />

trend to increased trade with poor countries and the fragmentation of the means of<br />

production, resulting in low skilled jobs becoming more tradeable. However, he<br />

concedes that the effect of trade on inequality in America is minor when compared to<br />

other causes, such as technological innovation, a view shared by other experts.<br />

Empirical economists Max Roser and Jesus Crespo-Cuaresma find support in the data<br />

that international trade is increasing income inequality. They empirically confirm the<br />

predictions of the Stolper–Samuelson theorem regarding the effects of international<br />

trade on the distribution of incomes. Lawrence Katz estimates that trade has only<br />

accounted for 5-15% of rising income inequality. Robert Lawrence argues that<br />

technological innovation and automation has meant that low-skilled jobs have been<br />

replaced by machine labor in wealthier nations, and that wealthier countries no longer<br />

have significant numbers of low-skilled manufacturing workers that could be affected by<br />

competition from poor countries.<br />

Page 47 of 181


Economist Branko Milanovic analyzed global income inequality, comparing 1988 and<br />

2008. His analysis indicated that the global top 1% and the middle classes of the<br />

emerging economies (e.g., China, India, Indonesia, Brazil and Egypt) were the main<br />

winners of globalization during that time. The real (inflation adjusted) income of the<br />

global top 1% increased approximately 60%, while the middle classes of the emerging<br />

economies (those around the 50th percentile of the global income distribution in 1988)<br />

rose 70-80%. On the other hand, those in the middle class of the developed world<br />

(those in the 75th to 90th percentile in 1988, such as the American middle class)<br />

experienced little real income gains. The richest 1% contains 60 million persons<br />

globally, including 30 million Americans (i.e., the top 12% of Americans by income were<br />

in the global top 1% in 2008).<br />

Jonathan Rothwell argues that there is a negative not a positive correlation between<br />

trade and inequality when different countries are compared. Trade makes up a relatively<br />

small part of the relatively unequal US economy, while Denmark and the Netherlands<br />

have high levels of both equality and dependence on imports.<br />

Gender<br />

The gender gap in median earnings of full-time<br />

employees according to the OECD 2015<br />

In many countries, there is a gender<br />

pay gap in favor of males in the labor<br />

market. Several factors other than<br />

discrimination may contribute to this<br />

gap. On average, women are more<br />

likely than men to consider factors<br />

other than pay when looking for<br />

work, and may be less willing to<br />

travel or relocate. Thomas Sowell, in his book Knowledge and Decisions, claims that<br />

this difference is due to women not taking jobs due to marriage or pregnancy, but<br />

income studies show that that does not explain the entire difference. A U.S. Census's<br />

report stated that in US once other factors are accounted for there is still a difference in<br />

earnings between women and men. The income gap in other countries ranges from<br />

53% in Botswana to -40% in Bahrain.<br />

Gender inequality and discrimination is argued to cause and perpetuate poverty and<br />

vulnerability in society as a whole. Gender Equity Indices seek to provide the tools to<br />

demonstrate this feature of equity.<br />

19th century socialists like Robert Owen, William Thompson, Anna Wheeler and August<br />

Bebel argued that the economic inequality between genders was the leading cause of<br />

economic inequality; however Karl Marx and Fredrick Engels believed that the inequality<br />

between social classes was the larger cause of inequality.<br />

Page 48 of 181


Economic Development<br />

A Kuznets Curve<br />

Economist Simon Kuznets argued that<br />

levels of economic inequality are in large<br />

part the result of stages of development.<br />

According to Kuznets, countries with low<br />

levels of development have relatively<br />

equal distributions of wealth. As a<br />

country develops, it acquires more<br />

capital, which leads to the owners of this<br />

capital having more wealth and income and introducing inequality. Eventually, through<br />

various possible redistribution mechanisms such as social welfare programs, more<br />

developed countries move back to lower levels of inequality.<br />

Plotting the relationship between level of income and inequality, Kuznets saw middleincome<br />

developing economies level of inequality bulging out to form what is now known<br />

as the Kuznets curve. Kuznets demonstrated this relationship using cross-sectional<br />

data. However, more recent testing of this theory with superior panel data has shown it<br />

to be very weak. Kuznets' curve predicts that income inequality will eventually decrease<br />

given time.<br />

As an example, income inequality did fall in the United States during its High school<br />

movement from 1910 to 1940 and thereafter. However, recent data shows that the level<br />

of income inequality began to rise after the 1970s. This does not necessarily disprove<br />

Kuznets' theory. It may be possible that another Kuznets' cycle is occurring, specifically<br />

the move from the manufacturing sector to the service sector. This implies that it may<br />

be possible for multiple Kuznets' cycles to be in effect at any given time.<br />

Individual Preferences<br />

Related to cultural issues, diversity of preferences within a society may contribute to<br />

economic inequality. When faced with the choice between working harder to earn more<br />

money or enjoying more leisure time, equally capable individuals with identical earning<br />

potential may choose different strategies. The trade-off between work and leisure is<br />

particularly important in the supply side of the labor market in labor economics.<br />

Likewise, individuals in a society often have different levels of risk aversion. When<br />

equally-able individuals undertake risky activities with the potential of large payoffs,<br />

such as starting new businesses, some ventures succeed and some fail. The presence<br />

of both successful and unsuccessful ventures in a society results in economic inequality<br />

even when all individuals are identical.<br />

Page 49 of 181


Wealth Concentration<br />

Wealth concentration is the process by which, under certain conditions, newly created<br />

wealth concentrates in the possession of already-wealthy individuals or entities.<br />

Accordingly, those who already hold wealth have the means to invest in new sources of<br />

creating wealth or to otherwise leverage the accumulation of wealth, thus are the<br />

beneficiaries of the new wealth. Over time, wealth condensation can significantly<br />

contribute to the persistence of inequality within society. Thomas Piketty in his book<br />

Capital in the Twenty-First Century argues that the fundamental force for divergence is<br />

the usually greater return of capital (r) than economic growth (g), and that larger<br />

fortunes generate higher returns.<br />

As of 2017, there were 2,754 U.S. dollar billionaires worldwide, with a combined wealth<br />

of over US$9.2 trillion, up from US$2.4 trillion in 2009.<br />

Rent Seeking<br />

Economist Joseph Stiglitz argues that rather than explaining concentrations of wealth<br />

and income, market forces should serve as a brake on such concentration, which may<br />

better be explained by the non-market force known as "rent-seeking". While the market<br />

will bid up compensation for rare and desired skills to reward wealth creation, greater<br />

productivity, etc., it will also prevent successful entrepreneurs from earning excess<br />

profits by fostering competition to cut prices, profits and large compensation. A better<br />

explainer of growing inequality, according to Stiglitz, is the use of political power<br />

generated by wealth by certain groups to shape government policies financially<br />

beneficial to them. This process, known to economists as rent-seeking, brings income<br />

not from creation of wealth but from "grabbing a larger share of the wealth that would<br />

otherwise have been produced without their effort"<br />

Rent seeking is often thought to be the province of societies with weak institutions and<br />

weak rule of law, but Stiglitz believes there is no shortage of it in developed societies<br />

such as the United States. Examples of rent seeking leading to inequality include:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

the obtaining of public resources by "rent-collectors" at below market prices<br />

(such as granting public land to railroads or selling mineral resources for a<br />

nominal price in the US)<br />

selling services and products to the public at above market prices (medicare drug<br />

benefit in the US that prohibits government from negotiating prices of drugs with<br />

the drug companies, costing the US government an estimated $50 billion or more<br />

per year)<br />

securing government tolerance of monopoly power (The richest person in the<br />

world in 2011, Carlos Slim, controlled Mexico's newly privatized<br />

telecommunication industry).<br />

Page 50 of 181


Since rent seeking aims to "pluck the goose to obtain the largest amount of feathers<br />

with the least possible amount of hissing" – it is by nature obscure, avoiding public<br />

spotlight in legal fine print, or camouflaged its extraction with widely accepted<br />

rationalizations (markets are naturally competitive and so need no government<br />

regulation against monopolies).<br />

Jonathan Rothwell also argues for rent seeking at least in the form of "regulatory<br />

barriers that shelter" the sectors of "professional services, finance and insurance, and<br />

health care" from competition are a major source of the growth in inequality, at least in<br />

the US.<br />

Finance Industry<br />

Jamie Galbraith argues that<br />

countries with larger financial<br />

sectors have greater<br />

inequality, and the link is not<br />

an accident.<br />

Effects<br />

Effects of inequality<br />

researchers have found<br />

include higher rates of health<br />

and social problems, and<br />

lower rates of social goods, a<br />

lower level of economic utility in society from resources devoted on high-end<br />

consumption, and even a lower level of economic growth when human capital is<br />

neglected for high-end consumption. For the top 21 industrialised countries, counting<br />

each person equally, life expectancy is lower in more unequal countries (r = -.907). A<br />

similar relationship exists among US states (r = -.620).<br />

2013 Economics Nobel prize winner Robert J. Shiller said that rising inequality in the<br />

United States and elsewhere is the most important problem.<br />

The economic stratification of society into "elites" and "masses" played a central role in<br />

the collapse of other advanced civilizations such as the Roman, Han and Gupta<br />

empires.<br />

Creation of The Welfare State<br />

Some, such as Alberto Alesina and Dani Rodrik, argue that economic inequality creates<br />

demand for redistribution and the creation of welfare states. A 2014 study questions this<br />

relationship, finding that "inequality did not favour the development of social policy<br />

between 1880 and 1930. On the contrary, social policy developed more easily in<br />

Page 51 of 181


countries that were previously more egalitarian, suggesting that unequal societies were<br />

in a sort of inequality trap, where inequality itself was an obstacle to redistribution."<br />

Democracy<br />

According to a 2017 review study in the Annual Review of Political Science by Stanford<br />

University political scientist Kenneth Scheve and New York University political scientist<br />

David Stasavage, "the simple conjectures that democracy produces wealth equality and<br />

that wealth inequality leads to democratic failure are not supported by the evidence."<br />

Health<br />

British researchers Richard G. Wilkinson and Kate Pickett have found higher rates of<br />

health and social problems (obesity, mental illness, homicides, teenage births,<br />

incarceration, child conflict, drug use), and lower rates of social goods (life expectancy<br />

by country, educational performance, trust among strangers, women's status, social<br />

mobility, even numbers of patents issued) in countries and states with higher inequality.<br />

Using statistics from 23 developed countries and the 50 states of the US, they found<br />

social/health problems lower in countries like Japan and Finland and states like Utah<br />

and New Hampshire with high levels of equality, than in countries (US and UK) and<br />

states (Mississippi and New York) with large differences in household income.<br />

For most of human history higher material living standards – full stomachs, access to<br />

clean water and warmth from fuel – led to better health and longer lives. This pattern of<br />

higher incomes-longer lives still holds among poorer countries, where life expectancy<br />

increases rapidly as per capita income increases, but in recent decades it has slowed<br />

down among middle income countries and plateaued among the richest thirty or so<br />

countries in the world. Americans live no longer on average (about 77 years in 2004)<br />

than Greeks (78 years) or New Zealanders (78), though the USA has a higher GDP per<br />

capita. Life expectancy in Sweden (80 years) and Japan (82) – where income was more<br />

equally distributed – was longer.<br />

In recent years the characteristic that has strongly correlated with health in developed<br />

countries is income inequality. Creating an index of "Health and Social Problems" from<br />

nine factors, authors Richard Wilkinson and Kate Pickett found health and social<br />

problems "more common in countries with bigger income inequalities", and more<br />

common among states in the US with larger income inequalities. Other studies have<br />

confirmed this relationship. The UNICEF index of "child well-being in rich countries",<br />

studying 40 indicators in 22 countries, correlates with greater equality but not per capita<br />

income.<br />

Pickett and Wilkinson argue that inequality and social stratification lead to higher levels<br />

of psychosocial stress and status anxiety which can lead to depression, chemical<br />

dependency, less community life, parenting problems and stress-related diseases.<br />

Page 52 of 181


In their book, Social Epidemiology, Ichiro Kawachi and S.V. Subramanian found that<br />

impoverished individuals simply cannot lead healthy lives as easily as the wealthy. They<br />

are unable to secure adequate nutrition for their families, cannot pay utility bills to keep<br />

themselves warm during the winter or cold during heat waves, and lack sufficient<br />

housing.<br />

National income inequality is positively<br />

related to the country's rate of<br />

schizophrenia.<br />

Social Cohesion<br />

Research has shown an inverse link<br />

between income inequality and<br />

social cohesion. In more equal<br />

societies, people are much more<br />

likely to trust each other,<br />

measures of social capital<br />

(the benefits of goodwill,<br />

fellowship, mutual<br />

sympathy and social<br />

connectedness<br />

among<br />

groups who<br />

make up a<br />

units)<br />

greater<br />

social<br />

suggest<br />

community<br />

involvement, and<br />

homicide rates are<br />

consistently lower.<br />

trust in<br />

Comparing results<br />

from the question<br />

"would others take<br />

advantage of you if<br />

they got the chance?"<br />

in U.S General Social<br />

Survey and statistics<br />

on income inequality,<br />

Eric Uslaner and<br />

Mitchell Brown found<br />

there is a high correlation between the amount of<br />

society and the amount of income equality. A<br />

Page 53 of 181


2008 article by Andersen and Fetner also found a strong relationship between economic<br />

inequality within and across countries and tolerance for 35 democracies.<br />

In two studies Robert Putnam established links between social capital and economic<br />

inequality. His most important studies established these links in both the United States<br />

and in Italy. His explanation for this relationship is that<br />

Community and equality are mutually reinforcing... Social capital and economic inequality<br />

moved in tandem through most of the twentieth century. In terms of the distribution of<br />

wealth and income, America in the 1950s and 1960s was more egalitarian than it had<br />

been in more than a century... [T]hose same decades were also the high point of social<br />

connectedness and civic engagement. Record highs in equality and social capital<br />

coincided. Conversely, the last third of the twentieth century was a time of growing<br />

inequality and eroding social capital... The timing of the two trends is striking: somewhere<br />

around 1965–70 America reversed course and started becoming both less just<br />

economically and less well connected socially and politically.<br />

Albrekt Larsen has advanced this explanation by a comparative study of how trust<br />

increased in Denmark and Sweden in the latter part of the 20th century while it<br />

decreased in the US and UK. It is argued that inequality levels influence how citizens<br />

imagine the trustworthiness of fellow citizens. In this model social trust is not about<br />

relations to people you meet (as in Putnam's model) but about people you imagine.<br />

The economist Joseph Stiglitz has argued that economic inequality has led to distrust of<br />

business and government.<br />

Crime<br />

Crime rate has also been shown to be correlated with inequality in society. Most studies<br />

looking into the relationship have concentrated on homicides – since homicides are<br />

almost identically defined across all nations and jurisdictions. There have been over fifty<br />

studies showing tendencies for violence to be more common in societies where income<br />

differences are larger. Research has been conducted comparing developed countries<br />

with undeveloped countries, as well as studying areas within countries. Daly et al. 2001<br />

found that among U.S. states and Canadian provinces there is a tenfold difference in<br />

homicide rates related to inequality. They estimated that about half of all variation in<br />

homicide rates can be accounted for by differences in the amount of inequality in each<br />

province or state. Fajnzylber et al. (2002) found a similar relationship worldwide. Among<br />

comments in academic literature on the relationship between homicides and inequality<br />

are:<br />

<br />

<br />

The most consistent finding in cross-national research on homicides has been<br />

that of a positive association between income inequality and homicides.<br />

Economic inequality is positively and significantly related to rates of homicide<br />

despite an extensive list of conceptually relevant controls. The fact that this<br />

relationship is found with the most recent data and using a different measure of<br />

Page 54 of 181


economic inequality from previous research, suggests that the finding is very<br />

robust.<br />

A 2016 study, controlling for different factors than previous studies, challenges the<br />

aforementioned findings. The study finds "little evidence of a significant empirical link<br />

between overall inequality and crime", and that "the previously reported positive<br />

correlation between violent crime and economic inequality is largely driven by economic<br />

segregation across neighborhoods instead of within-neighborhood inequality".<br />

Social, Cultural, and Civic Participation<br />

Higher income inequality led to less of all forms of social, cultural, and civic participation<br />

among the less wealthy. When inequality is higher the poor do not shift to less<br />

expensive forms of participation.<br />

Utility, Economic Welfare, and Distributive Efficiency<br />

Following the utilitarian principle of seeking the greatest good for the greatest number –<br />

economic inequality is problematic. A house that provides less utility to a millionaire as a<br />

summer home than it would to a homeless family of five, is an example of reduced<br />

"distributive efficiency" within society, that decreases marginal utility of wealth and thus<br />

the sum total of personal utility. An additional dollar spent by a poor person will go to<br />

things providing a great deal of utility to that person, such as basic necessities like food,<br />

water, and healthcare; while, an additional dollar spent by a much richer person will very<br />

likely go to luxury items providing relatively less utility to that person. Thus, the marginal<br />

utility of wealth per person ("the additional dollar") decreases as a person becomes<br />

richer. From this standpoint, for any given amount of wealth in society, a society with<br />

more equality will have higher aggregate utility. Some studies have found evidence for<br />

Page 55 of 181


this theory, noting that in societies where inequality is lower, population-wide<br />

satisfaction and happiness tend to be higher.<br />

Philosopher David Schmidtz argues that maximizing the sum of individual utilities will<br />

harm incentives to produce.<br />

A society that takes Joe Rich's second unit [of corn] is taking that unit away from<br />

someone who . . . has nothing better to do than plant it and giving it to someone who . .<br />

. does have something better to do with it. That sounds good, but in the process, the<br />

society takes seed corn out of production and diverts it to food, thereby cannibalizing<br />

itself.<br />

However, in addition to the diminishing marginal utility of unequal distribution, Pigou and<br />

others point out that a "keeping up with the Joneses" effect among the well off may lead<br />

to greater inequality and use of resources for no greater return in utility.<br />

A larger proportion of the satisfaction yielded by the incomes of rich people comes from<br />

their relative, rather than from their absolute, amount. This part of it will not be<br />

destroyed if the incomes of all rich people are diminished together. The loss of<br />

economic welfare suffered by the rich when command over resources is transferred<br />

from them to the poor will, therefore, be substantially smaller relatively to the gain of<br />

economic welfare to the poor than a consideration of the law of diminishing utility taken<br />

by itself suggests.<br />

When the goal is to own the biggest yacht – rather than a boat with certain features –<br />

there is no greater benefit from owning 100 metre long boat than a 20 m one as long as<br />

it is bigger than your rival. Economist Robert H. Frank compare the situation to that of<br />

male elks who use their antlers to spar with other males for mating rights.<br />

The pressure to have bigger ones than your rivals leads to an arms race that consumes<br />

resources that could have been used more efficiently for other things, such as fighting<br />

off disease. As a result, every male ends up with a cumbersome and expensive pair of<br />

antlers, ... and "life is more miserable for bull elk as a group."<br />

Aggregate Demand, Consumption and Debt<br />

Conservative researchers have argued that income inequality is not significant because<br />

consumption, rather than income should be the measure of inequality, and inequality of<br />

consumption is less extreme than inequality of income in the US. According to Johnson,<br />

Smeeding, and Tory, consumption inequality was actually lower in 2001 than it was in<br />

1986. The debate is summarized in "The Hidden Prosperity of the Poor" by journalist<br />

Thomas B. Edsall. Other studies have not found consumption inequality less dramatic<br />

than household income inequality, and the CBO's study found consumption data not<br />

"adequately" capturing "consumption by high-income households" as it does their<br />

income, though it did agree that household consumption numbers show more equal<br />

distribution than household income.<br />

Page 56 of 181


Others dispute the importance of consumption over income, pointing out that if middle<br />

and lower income are consuming more than they earn it is because they are saving less<br />

or going deeper into debt. Income inequality has been the driving factor in the growing<br />

household debt, as high earners bid up the price of real estate and middle income<br />

earners go deeper into debt trying to maintain what once was a middle class lifestyle.<br />

Central Banking economist<br />

Raghuram Rajan argues that<br />

"systematic economic inequalities,<br />

within the United States and around<br />

the world, have created deep<br />

financial 'fault lines' that have made<br />

[financial] crises more likely to<br />

happen than in the past" – the<br />

Financial crisis of 2007–08 being<br />

the most recent example. To<br />

compensate for stagnating and<br />

declining purchasing power, political pressure has developed to extend easier credit to<br />

the lower and middle income earners – particularly to buy homes – and easier credit in<br />

general to keep unemployment rates low. This has given the American economy a<br />

tendency to go "from bubble to bubble" fueled by unsustainable monetary stimulation.<br />

Monopolization of Labor, Consolidation, and Competition<br />

Greater income inequality can lead to monopolization of the labor force, resulting in<br />

fewer employers requiring fewer workers. Remaining employers can consolidate and<br />

take advantage of the relative lack of competition, leading to less consumer choice,<br />

market abuses, and relatively higher real prices.<br />

Economic Incentives<br />

Some economists believe that one of the main reasons that inequality might induce<br />

economic incentive is because material well-being and conspicuous consumption relate<br />

to status. In this view, high stratification of income (high inequality) creates high<br />

amounts of social stratification, leading to greater competition for status.<br />

One of the first writers to note this relationship, Adam Smith, recognized "regard" as one<br />

of the major driving forces behind economic activity. From The Theory of Moral<br />

Sentiments in 1759:<br />

[W]hat is the end of avarice and ambition, of the pursuit of wealth, of power, and preeminence?<br />

Is it to supply the necessities of nature? The wages of the meanest labourer<br />

can supply them... [W]hy should those who have been educated in the higher ranks of<br />

life, regard it as worse than death, to be reduced to live, even without labour, upon the<br />

same simple fare with him, to dwell under the same lowly roof, and to be clothed in the<br />

Page 57 of 181


same humble attire? From whence, then, arises that emulation which runs through all<br />

the different ranks of men, and what are the advantages which we propose by that great<br />

purpose of human life which we call bettering our condition? To be observed, to be<br />

attended to, to be taken notice of with sympathy, complacency, and approbation, are all<br />

the advantages which we can propose to derive from it. It is the vanity, not the ease, or<br />

the pleasure, which interests us.<br />

Modern sociologists and economists such as Juliet Schor and Robert H. Frank have<br />

studied the extent to which economic activity is fueled by the ability of consumption to<br />

represent social status. Schor, in The Overspent American, argues that the increasing<br />

inequality during the 1980s and 1990s strongly accounts for increasing aspirations of<br />

income, increased consumption, decreased savings, and increased debt.<br />

In the book Luxury Fever, Robert H. Frank argues that satisfaction with levels of income<br />

is much more strongly affected by how someone's income compares with others than its<br />

absolute level. Frank gives the example of instructions to a yacht architect by a<br />

customer – shipping magnate Stavros Niarchos – to make Niarchos' new yacht 50 feet<br />

longer than that of rival magnate Aristotle Onassis. Niarchos did not specify or<br />

reportedly even know the exact length of Onassis's yacht.<br />

Pre-2000 Studies<br />

Economic Growth<br />

A 1999 review in the Journal of Economic Literature states high inequality lowers<br />

growth, perhaps because it increases social and political instability. The article also<br />

says:<br />

Somewhat unusually for the growth literature, studies have tended to concur in finding a<br />

negative effect of high inequality on subsequent growth. The evidence has not been<br />

accepted by all: some writers point out the concentration of richer countries at the lower<br />

end of the inequality spectrum, the poor quality of the distribution data, and the lack of<br />

robustness to fixed effects specifications. At least, though, it has become extremely<br />

difficult to build a case that inequality is good for growth. This in itself represents a<br />

considerable advance. Given the indications that inequality is harmful for growth,<br />

attention has moved on to the likely mechanisms.... the literature seems to be moving ...<br />

towards an examination of the effects of inequality on fertility rates, investment in<br />

education, and political stability.<br />

A 1992 World Bank report published in the Journal of Development Economics said that<br />

Inequality is negatively, and robustly, correlated with growth. This result is not highly<br />

dependent upon assumptions about either the form of the growth regression or the<br />

measure of inequality...Although statistically significant, the magnitude of the<br />

relationship between inequality and growth is relatively small.<br />

Page 58 of 181


NYU economist William Baumol found that substantial inequality does not stimulate<br />

growth because poverty reduces labor force productivity. Economists Dierk Herzer and<br />

Sebastian Vollmer found that increased income inequality reduces economic growth,<br />

but growth itself increases income inequality.<br />

Berg and Ostry of the International Monetary Fund found that of the factors affecting the<br />

duration of growth spells (not the rate of growth) in developed and developing countries,<br />

income equality is more beneficial than trade openness, sound political institutions, or<br />

foreign investment.<br />

In 1993, Galor and Zeira showed that inequality in the presence of credit market<br />

imperfections has a long lasting detrimental effect on human capital formation and<br />

economic development. A 1996 study by Perotti examined the channels through which<br />

inequality may affect economic growth. He showed that, in accordance with the credit<br />

market imperfection approach, inequality is associated with lower level of human capital<br />

formation (education, experience, and apprenticeship) and higher level of fertility, and<br />

thereby lower levels of growth. He found that inequality is associated with higher levels<br />

of redistributive taxation, which is associated with lower levels of growth from reductions<br />

in private savings and investment. Perotti concluded that, "more equal societies have<br />

lower fertility rates and higher rates of investment in education. Both are reflected in<br />

higher rates of growth. Also, very unequal societies tend to be politically and socially<br />

unstable, which is reflected in lower rates of investment and therefore growth."<br />

Research by Harvard economist Robert Barro, found that there is "little overall relation<br />

between income inequality and rates of growth and investment". According to work by<br />

Barro in 1999 and 2000, high levels of inequality reduce growth in relatively poor<br />

countries but encourage growth in richer countries. A study of Swedish counties<br />

between 1960 and 2000 found a positive impact of inequality on growth with lead times<br />

Page 59 of 181


of five years or less, but no correlation after ten years. Studies of larger data sets have<br />

found no correlations for any fixed lead time, and a negative impact on the duration of<br />

growth.<br />

Some theories developed in the 1970s established possible avenues through which<br />

inequality may have a positive effect on economic development. According to a 1955<br />

review, savings by the wealthy, if these increase with inequality, were thought to offset<br />

reduced consumer demand.<br />

Post-2000 Studies<br />

According to International Monetary Fund economists, inequality in wealth and income<br />

is negatively correlated with the duration of economic growth spells (not the rate of<br />

growth). High levels of inequality prevent not just economic prosperity, but also the<br />

quality of a country's institutions and high levels of education. According to IMF staff<br />

economists, "if the income share of the top 20 percent (the rich) increases, then GDP<br />

growth actually declines over the medium term, suggesting that the benefits do not<br />

trickle down. In contrast, an increase in the income share of the bottom 20 percent (the<br />

poor) is associated with higher GDP growth. The poor and the middle class matter the<br />

most for growth via a number of interrelated economic, social, and political channels."<br />

However, further work done in 2015 by Sutirtha Bagchia and Jan Svejnar suggests that<br />

it is only inequality caused by corruption and cronyism that harms growth. When they<br />

control for the fact that some inequality is caused by billionaires using their political<br />

connections, then inequality caused by market forces does not seem to have an effect<br />

on growth.<br />

Economist Joseph Stiglitz presented evidence in 2009 that both global inequality and<br />

inequality within countries prevent growth by limiting aggregate demand. Economist<br />

Branko Milanovic, wrote in 2001 that, "The view that income inequality harms growth –<br />

or that improved equality can help sustain growth – has become more widely held in<br />

recent years. ... The main reason for this shift is the increasing importance of human<br />

capital in development. When physical capital mattered most, savings and investments<br />

were key. Then it was important to have a large contingent of rich people who could<br />

save a greater proportion of their income than the poor and invest it in physical capital.<br />

But now that human capital is scarcer than machines, widespread education has<br />

become the secret to growth."<br />

Studies on income inequality and growth have sometimes found evidence confirming<br />

the Kuznets curve hypothesis, which states that with economic development, inequality<br />

first increases, then decreases. Economist Thomas Piketty challenges this notion,<br />

claiming that from 1914 to 1945 wars and "violent economic and political shocks"<br />

reduced inequality. Moreover, Piketty argues that the "magical" Kuznets curve<br />

hypothesis, with its emphasis on the balancing of economic growth in the long run,<br />

cannot account for the significant increase in economic inequality throughout the<br />

developed world since the 1970s. However, Kristin Forbes found that if country-specific<br />

Page 60 of 181


effects were eliminated by using panel estimation, then income inequality does have a<br />

significant positive relationship with economic growth. This relationship held across<br />

different "samples, variable definitions, and model specifications." Historian Walter<br />

Scheidel, who builds on Piketty's thesis that it has been violent shocks that have<br />

reduced inequality in The Great Leveler (2017), contends that "the preponderance of<br />

the evidence fails to support the idea of a systematic relationship between economic<br />

growth and income inequality as first envisioned by Kuznets sixty years ago."<br />

A 2012 study published by Inyong Shin of Asia University found that economic<br />

inequality in the developed world has a very different effect on economic growth than in<br />

the developing world, saying that "higher inequality can retard growth in the early stage<br />

of economic development", but that "higher inequality can encourage growth in a near<br />

steady state".<br />

A 2013 report on Nigeria suggests that growth has risen with increased income<br />

inequality. Some theories popular from the 1950s to 2011 argued that inequality had a<br />

positive effect on economic development. However, Abhijit Banerjee and Esther Duflo<br />

argue that analyses based on comparing yearly equality figures to yearly growth rates<br />

were misleading because it takes several years for effects to manifest as changes to<br />

economic growth. IMF economists found a strong association between lower levels of<br />

inequality in developing countries and sustained periods of economic growth.<br />

Developing countries with high inequality have "succeeded in initiating growth at high<br />

Page 61 of 181


ates for a few years" but "longer growth spells are robustly associated with more<br />

equality in the income distribution."<br />

An OECD study in 2015, found that internationally "countries where income inequality is<br />

decreasing grow faster than those with rising inequality", and noted that "a lack of<br />

investment in education by the poor is the main factor behind inequality hurting growth"<br />

A 2016 meta-analysis found that "the effect of inequality on growth is negative and more<br />

pronounced in less developed countries than in rich countries".<br />

A 2017 study argued that there were both positive and negative effects of inequality:<br />

"When inequality is associated with political instability and social unrest, rent seeking<br />

and distortive policies, lower capacities for investment in human capital, and a stagnant<br />

domestic market, it is mostly expected to harm long-run economic performance, as<br />

suggested by many authors. Accordingly, improving income distribution is expected to<br />

foster long-run economic growth, especially in low-income countries where the levels of<br />

inequality are usually very high. However, some degree of inequality can also be good,<br />

as has been theoretically argued in the literature and as empirically suggested in this<br />

study. A degree of inequality can play a beneficial role for economic growth when that<br />

inequality is driven by market forces and related to hard work and growth-enhancing<br />

incentives like risk taking, innovation, capital investment, and agglomeration economies.<br />

The challenge for policy makers is to control structural inequality, which reduces the<br />

country's capacities for economic development, while at the same time keeping in place<br />

those positive incentives that are also necessary for growth."<br />

Mechanisms<br />

According to economist Branko Milanovic, while traditionally economists thought<br />

inequality was good for growth<br />

The view that income inequality harms growth – or that improved equality can help<br />

sustain growth – has become more widely held in recent years. ... The main reason for<br />

this shift is the increasing importance of human capital in development. When physical<br />

capital mattered most, savings and investments were key. Then it was important to<br />

have a large contingent of rich people who could save a greater proportion of their<br />

income than the poor and invest it in physical capital. But now that human capital is<br />

scarcer than machines, widespread education has become the secret to growth.<br />

"Broadly accessible education" is both difficult to achieve when income distribution is<br />

uneven and tends to reduce "income gaps between skilled and unskilled labor."<br />

The sovereign-debt economic problems of the late twenty-oughts do not seem to be<br />

correlated to redistribution policies in Europe. With the exception of Ireland, the<br />

countries at risk of default in 2011 (Greece, Italy, Spain, Portugal) were notable for their<br />

high Gini-measured levels of income inequality compared to other European countries.<br />

As measured by the Gini index, Greece as of 2008 had more income inequality than the<br />

economically healthy Germany.<br />

Page 62 of 181


Equitable Growth<br />

While acknowledging the central role economic growth can potentially play in human<br />

development, poverty reduction and the achievement of the Millennium Development<br />

Goals, it is becoming widely understood among the development community that<br />

special efforts must be made to ensure poorer sections of society are able to participate<br />

in economic growth. The effect of economic growth on poverty reduction – the growth<br />

elasticity of poverty – can depend on the existing level of inequality. For instance, with<br />

low inequality a country with a growth rate of 2% per head and 40% of its population<br />

living in poverty, can halve poverty in ten years, but a country with high inequality would<br />

take nearly 60 years to achieve the same reduction. In the words of the Secretary<br />

General of the United Nations Ban Ki-Moon: "While economic growth is necessary, it is<br />

not sufficient for progress on reducing poverty." Competition policy intending to prevent<br />

companies from abusing market power contributes to inclusive growth.<br />

Housing<br />

In many poor and developing countries, much land and housing is held outside the<br />

formal or legal property ownership registration system. Much unregistered property is<br />

held in informal form through various associations and other arrangements. Reasons for<br />

extra-legal ownership include excessive bureaucratic red tape in buying property and<br />

building, In some countries it can take over 200 steps and up to 14 years to build on<br />

government land. Other causes of extra-legal property are failures to notarize<br />

transaction documents or having documents notarized but failing to have them recorded<br />

with the official agency.<br />

Page 63 of 181


Rent controls in Brazil dramatically reduced the percentage of legal housing compared<br />

to extra-legal housing, which had a much better supply to demand balance.<br />

A number of researchers (David Rodda, Jacob Vigdor, and Janna Matlack), argue that a<br />

shortage of affordable housing – at least in the US – is caused in part by income<br />

inequality. David Rodda noted that from 1984 and 1991, the number of quality rental<br />

units decreased as the demand for higher quality housing increased (Rhoda 1994:148).<br />

Through gentrification of older neighborhoods, for example, in East New York, rental<br />

prices increased rapidly as landlords found new residents willing to pay higher market<br />

rate for housing and left lower income families without rental units. The ad valorem<br />

property tax policy combined with rising prices made it difficult or impossible for low<br />

income residents to keep pace.<br />

Aspirational Consumption and Household Risk<br />

Firstly, certain costs are difficult to avoid and are shared by everyone, such as the costs<br />

of housing, pensions, education and health care. If the state does not provide these<br />

services, then for those on lower incomes, the costs must be borrowed and often those<br />

on lower incomes are those who are worse equipped to manage their finances.<br />

Secondly, aspirational consumption describes the process of middle income earners<br />

aspiring to achieve the standards of living enjoyed by their wealthier counterparts and<br />

one method of achieving this aspiration is by taking on debt. The result leads to even<br />

greater inequality and potential economic instability.<br />

Poverty<br />

Oxfam asserts that worsening inequality is impeding the fight against global poverty. A<br />

2013 report from the group stated that the $240 billion added to the fortunes of the<br />

world's richest billionaires in 2012 was enough to end extreme poverty four times over.<br />

Oxfam Executive Director Jeremy Hobbs said that "We can no longer pretend that the<br />

creation of wealth for a few will inevitably benefit the many – too often the reverse is<br />

true."<br />

Jared Bernstein and Elise Gould of the Economic Policy Institute suggest that poverty in<br />

the United States could have been significantly mitigated if inequality had not increased<br />

over the last few decades.<br />

Environment<br />

Multiple arguments can be made about the relationship between poverty and the<br />

environment. In some cases, alleviating poverty can result in detrimental environmental<br />

affects or exacerbate degradation; the smaller the economic inequality, the more waste<br />

and pollution is created, resulting in many cases, in more environmental degradation.<br />

This can be explained by the fact that as the poor people in the society become more<br />

wealthy, it increases their yearly carbon emissions. This relation is expressed by the<br />

Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC). It should be noted here however that in certain<br />

Page 64 of 181


cases, with great economic inequality, there is nonetheless not more waste and<br />

pollution created as the waste/pollution is cleaned up better afterwards (water<br />

treatment, filtering, ... ) Also note that the whole of the increase in environmental<br />

degradation is the result of the increase of emissions per person being multiplied by a<br />

multiplier. If there were fewer people, however, this multiplier would be lower, and thus<br />

the amount of environmental degradation would be lower as well. As such, the current<br />

high level of population has a large impact on this as well. If (as WWF argued),<br />

population levels would start to drop to a sustainable level (1/3 of current levels, so<br />

about 2 billion people), human inequality can be addressed/corrected, while still not<br />

resulting in an increase of environmental damage.<br />

On the other hand, other sources argue that alleviating poverty will reap positive<br />

progressions on the environment, especially with technological advances in energy<br />

efficiency. Urbanization, for instance, can "reduce the area in which humans impact the<br />

environment, thereby protecting nature elsewhere." Through concentration human<br />

societies, urbanized regions can allow for more allocated reserves for wildlife.<br />

Moreover, through urbanization, such societies have a higher standard of living that can<br />

promote environmental health with better food, technology, education, and more. The<br />

argument that links poverty alleviation to environmental conservation outlines the idea<br />

Page 65 of 181


that "gross inequalities that exist between rich and poor in the world have created a<br />

situation where many people have to sacrifice environmental thinking just to stay alive."<br />

Political Influence<br />

In 2015, a study by Lahtinen and Wass suggested that low social mobility reduces<br />

turnout among lower classes.<br />

War, Terrorism and Political Instability<br />

One study finds that income inequality increases political instability: "more unequal<br />

societies are more politically unstable". A 2016 study finds that interregional inequality<br />

increases terrorism. Another 2016 study finds that inequality between social classes<br />

increases the likelihood of coups but not civil wars. A lack of reliable data makes it<br />

difficult to study the relationship between inequality and political violence.<br />

John A. Hobson, Rosa Luxemburg, and Vladimir Lenin argued that WWI was caused by<br />

inequality. Economist Branko Milanovic claims that there is credence to this argument in<br />

his 2016 book Global Inequality: A New Approach for the Age of Globalization.<br />

Fairness vs. Equality<br />

Perspectives<br />

According to Christina Starmans et al. (Nature Hum. Beh., 2017), the research literature<br />

contains no evidence on people having an aversion on inequality. In all studies<br />

analyzed, the subjects preferred fair distributions to equal distributions, in both<br />

laboratory and real-world situations. In public, researchers may loosely speak of<br />

equality instead of fairness, when referring to studies where fairness happens to<br />

coincide with equality, but in many studies fairness is carefully separated from equality<br />

and the results are univocal. Already very young children seem to prefer fairness over<br />

equality.<br />

When people were asked, what would be the wealth of each quintile in their ideal<br />

society, they gave a 50-fold sum to the richest quintile than to the poorest quintile. The<br />

preference for inequality increases in adolescence, and so do the capabilities to favor<br />

fortune, effort and ability in the distribution.<br />

Preference for unequal distribution has been developed to the human race possibly<br />

because it allows for better co-operation and allows a person to work with a more<br />

productive person so that both parties benefit from the co-operation. Inequality also<br />

solves the problems of free-riders, cheaters and ill-behaving people.<br />

In many societies, such as the USSR, the distribution lead to anger, as it was felt too<br />

equal, unfair. In the current U.S., many feel that the distribution is unfair in being too<br />

Page 66 of 181


unequal. In both cases, the cause is unfairness, not inequality, the researchers<br />

conclude.<br />

Socialist Perspectives<br />

Socialists attribute the vast disparities in wealth to the private ownership of the means of<br />

production by a class of owners, creating a situation where a small portion of the<br />

population lives off unearned property income by virtue of ownership titles in capital<br />

equipment, financial assets and corporate stock. By contrast, the vast majority of the<br />

population is dependent on income in the form of a wage or salary. In order to rectify<br />

this situation, socialists argue that the means of production should be socially owned so<br />

that income differentials would be reflective of individual contributions to the social<br />

product.<br />

Marxist socialists ultimately predict the emergence of a communist society based on the<br />

common ownership of the means of production, where each individual citizen would<br />

have free access to the articles of consumption (From each according to his ability, to<br />

each according to his need). According to Marxist philosophy, equality in the sense of<br />

free access is essential for freeing individuals from dependent relationships, thereby<br />

allowing them to transcend alienation.<br />

Meritocracy<br />

Meritocracy favors an eventual society where an individual's success is a direct function<br />

of his merit, or contribution. Economic inequality would be a natural consequence of the<br />

wide range in individual skill, talent and effort in human population. David Landes stated<br />

Page 67 of 181


that the progression of Western economic development that led to the Industrial<br />

Revolution was facilitated by men advancing through their own merit rather than<br />

because of family or political connections.<br />

Liberal Perspectives<br />

Most modern social liberals, including centrist or left-of-center political groups, believe<br />

that the capitalist economic system should be fundamentally preserved, but the status<br />

quo regarding the income gap must be reformed. Social liberals favor a capitalist<br />

system with active Keynesian macroeconomic policies and progressive taxation (to<br />

even out differences in income inequality).<br />

However, contemporary classical liberals and libertarians generally do not take a stance<br />

on wealth inequality, but believe in equality under the law regardless of whether it leads<br />

to unequal wealth distribution. In 1966 Ludwig von Mises, a prominent figure in the<br />

Austrian School of economic thought, explains:<br />

The liberal champions of equality under the law were fully aware of the fact that men are<br />

born unequal and that it is precisely their inequality that generates social cooperation<br />

and civilization. Equality under the law was in their opinion not designed to correct the<br />

inexorable facts of the universe and to make natural inequality disappear. It was, on the<br />

contrary, the device to secure for the whole of mankind the maximum of benefits it can<br />

derive from it. Henceforth no man-made institutions should prevent a man from attaining<br />

that station in which he can best serve his fellow citizens.<br />

Robert Nozick argued that government redistributes wealth by force (usually in the form<br />

of taxation), and that the ideal moral society would be one where all individuals are free<br />

from force. However, Nozick recognized that some modern economic inequalities were<br />

the result of forceful taking of property, and a certain amount of redistribution would be<br />

justified to compensate for this force but not because of the inequalities themselves.<br />

John Rawls argued in A Theory of Justice that inequalities in the distribution of wealth<br />

are only justified when they improve society as a whole, including the poorest members.<br />

Rawls does not discuss the full implications of his theory of justice. Some see Rawls's<br />

argument as a justification for capitalism since even the poorest members of society<br />

theoretically benefit from increased innovations under capitalism; others believe only a<br />

strong welfare state can satisfy Rawls's theory of justice.<br />

Classical liberal Milton Friedman believed that if government action is taken in pursuit of<br />

economic equality then political freedom would suffer. In a famous quote, he said:<br />

A society that puts equality before freedom will get neither. A society that puts freedom<br />

before equality will get a high degree of both.<br />

Economist Tyler Cowen has argued that though income inequality has increased within<br />

nations, globally it has fallen over the last 20 years. He argues that though income<br />

inequality may make individual nations worse off, overall, the world has improved as<br />

global inequality has been reduced.<br />

Page 68 of 181


Social Justice Arguments<br />

Patrick Diamond and Anthony Giddens (professors of Economics and Sociology,<br />

respectively) hold that 'pure meritocracy is incoherent because, without redistribution,<br />

one generation's successful individuals would become the next generation's embedded<br />

caste, hoarding the wealth they had accumulated'.<br />

They also state that social justice requires redistribution of high incomes and large<br />

concentrations of wealth in a way that spreads it more widely, in order to "recognise the<br />

contribution made by all sections of the community to building the nation's wealth."<br />

(Patrick Diamond and Anthony Giddens, June 27, 2005, New Statesman)<br />

Pope Francis stated in his Evangelii gaudium, that "as long as the problems of the poor<br />

are not radically resolved by rejecting the absolute autonomy of markets and financial<br />

speculation and by attacking the structural causes of inequality, no solution will be found<br />

for the world's problems or, for that matter, to any problems." He later declared that<br />

"inequality is the root of social evil."<br />

When income inequality is low, aggregate demand will be relatively high, because more<br />

people who want ordinary consumer goods and services will be able to afford them,<br />

while the labor force will not be as relatively monopolized by the wealthy.<br />

Page 69 of 181


Effects on Social Welfare<br />

In most western democracies, the desire to eliminate or reduce economic inequality is<br />

generally associated with the political left. One practical argument in favor of reduction<br />

is the idea that economic inequality reduces social cohesion and increases social<br />

unrest, thereby weakening the society. There is evidence that this is true (see inequity<br />

aversion) and it is intuitive, at least for small face-to-face groups of people. Alberto<br />

Alesina, Rafael Di Tella, and Robert MacCulloch find that inequality negatively affects<br />

happiness in Europe but not in the United States.<br />

It has also been argued that economic inequality invariably translates to political<br />

inequality, which further aggravates the problem. Even in cases where an increase in<br />

economic inequality makes nobody economically poorer, an increased inequality of<br />

resources is disadvantageous, as increased economic inequality can lead to a power<br />

shift due to an increased inequality in the ability to participate in democratic processes.<br />

Capabilities Approach<br />

The capabilities approach – sometimes called the human development approach –<br />

looks at income inequality and poverty as form of "capability deprivation". Unlike<br />

neoliberalism, which "defines well-being as utility maximization", economic growth and<br />

income are considered a means to an end rather than the end itself. Its goal is to<br />

"wid[en] people's choices and the level of their achieved well-being" through increasing<br />

functionings (the things a person values doing), capabilities (the freedom to enjoy<br />

functionings) and agency (the ability to pursue valued goals).<br />

When a person's capabilities are lowered, they are in some way deprived of earning as<br />

much income as they would otherwise. An old, ill man cannot earn as much as a<br />

healthy young man; gender roles and customs may prevent a woman from receiving an<br />

education or working outside the home. There may be an epidemic that causes<br />

widespread panic, or there could be rampant violence in the area that prevents people<br />

from going to work for fear of their lives. As a result, income and economic inequality<br />

increases, and it becomes more difficult to reduce the gap without additional aid. To<br />

prevent such inequality, this approach believes it's important to have political freedom,<br />

economic facilities, social opportunities, transparency guarantees, and protective<br />

security to ensure that people aren't denied their functionings, capabilities, and agency<br />

and can thus work towards a better relevant income.<br />

Policy Responses Intended to Mitigate<br />

No business which depends for existence on paying less than living wages to its<br />

workers has any right to continue in this country.<br />

—President Franklin Delano Roosevelt, 1933<br />

A 2011 OECD study makes a number of suggestions to its member countries, including:<br />

Page 70 of 181


Well-targeted income-support policies.<br />

Facilitate and encourage access to employment.<br />

Better job-related training and education for the low-skilled (on-the-job training)<br />

would help to boost their productivity potential and future earnings.<br />

Better access to formal education.<br />

Progressive taxation reduces absolute income inequality when the higher rates on<br />

higher-income individuals are paid and not evaded, and transfer payments and social<br />

safety nets result in progressive government spending. Wage ratio legislation has also<br />

been proposed as a means of reducing income inequality. The OECD asserts that<br />

public spending is vital in reducing the ever-expanding wealth gap.<br />

The economists Emmanuel Saez and Thomas Piketty recommend much higher top<br />

marginal tax rates on the wealthy, up to 50 percent, or 70 percent or even 90 percent.<br />

Ralph Nader, Jeffrey Sachs, the United Front Against Austerity, among others, call for a<br />

financial transactions tax (also known as the Robin Hood tax) to bolster the social safety<br />

net and the public sector.<br />

Page 71 of 181


The Economist wrote in December 2013: "A minimum wage, providing it is not set too<br />

high, could thus boost pay with no ill effects on jobs....America's federal minimum wage,<br />

at 38% of median income, is one of the rich world's lowest. Some studies find no harm<br />

to employment from federal of state minimum wages, others see a small one, but none<br />

finds any serious damage."<br />

General limitations on and taxation of rent-seeking are popular across the political<br />

spectrum.<br />

Public policy responses addressing causes and effects of income inequality in the US<br />

include: progressive tax incidence adjustments, strengthening social safety net<br />

provisions such as Aid to Families with Dependent Children, welfare, the food stamp<br />

program, Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid, organizing community interest<br />

groups, increasing and reforming higher education subsidies, increasing infrastructure<br />

spending, and placing limits on and taxing rent-seeking.<br />

A 2017 study in the Journal of Political Economy by Daron Acemogu, James Robinson<br />

and Thierry Verdier argues that American "cutthroat" capitalism and inequality gives rise<br />

to technology and innovation that more "cuddly" forms of capitalism cannot. As a result,<br />

"the diversity of institutions we observe among relatively advanced countries, ranging<br />

from greater inequality and risk-taking in the United States to the more egalitarian<br />

societies supported by a strong safety net in Scandinavia, rather than reflecting<br />

differences in fundamentals between the citizens of these societies, may emerge as a<br />

mutually self-reinforcing world equilibrium. If so, in this equilibrium, "we cannot all be like<br />

the Scandinavians," because Scandinavian capitalism depends in part on the<br />

knowledge spillovers created by the more cutthroat American capitalism." A 2012<br />

working paper by the same authors, making similar arguments, was challenged by Lane<br />

Kenworthy, who posited that, among other things, the Nordic countries are consistently<br />

ranked as some of the world's most innovative countries by the World Economic<br />

Forum's Global Competitiveness Index, with Sweden ranking as the most innovative<br />

nation, followed by Finland, for 2012–2013; the U.S. ranked sixth.<br />

Mitigating Factors<br />

Countries with a left-leaning legislature generally have lower levels of inequality. Many<br />

factors constrain economic inequality – they may be divided into two classes:<br />

government sponsored, and market driven. The relative merits and effectiveness of<br />

each approach is a subject of debate.<br />

Typical government initiatives to reduce economic inequality include:<br />

<br />

Public education: increasing the supply of skilled labor and reducing income<br />

inequality due to education differentials.<br />

Page 72 of 181


Progressive taxation: the rich are taxed proportionally more than the poor,<br />

reducing the amount of income inequality in society if the change in taxation does<br />

not cause changes in income.<br />

Market forces outside of government intervention that can reduce economic inequality<br />

include:<br />

<br />

propensity to spend: with rising wealth & income, a person may spend more. In<br />

an extreme example, if one person owned everything, they would immediately<br />

need to hire people to maintain their properties, thus reducing the wealth<br />

concentration.<br />

Research shows that since 1300, the only periods with significant declines in wealth<br />

inequality in Europe were the Black Death and the two World Wars. Historian Walter<br />

Scheidel posits that, since the stone age, only extreme violence, catastrophes and<br />

upheaval in the form of total war, Communist revolution, pestilence and state collapse<br />

have significantly reduced inequality.<br />

He has stated that "only all-out thermonuclear war might fundamentally reset the<br />

existing distribution of resources" and that "peaceful policy reform may well prove<br />

unequal to the growing challenges ahead."<br />

________<br />

Page 73 of 181


Redlining<br />

In the United States and Canada, redlining is the systematic denial of various services<br />

to residents of specific, often racially associated, neighborhoods or communities, either<br />

directly or through the selective raising of prices. While the best known examples of<br />

redlining have involved denial of financial services such as banking or insurance, other<br />

services such as health care or even supermarkets have been denied to residents. In<br />

the case of retail businesses like supermarkets, purposely locating impractically far<br />

away from said residents results in a redlining effect. Reverse redlining occurs when a<br />

lender or insurer targets particular neighborhoods that are predominantly nonwhite, not<br />

to deny residents loans or insurance, but rather to charge them more than in a nonredlined<br />

neighborhood where there is more competition.<br />

In the 1960s, sociologist John McKnight coined the term "redlining" to describe the<br />

discriminatory practice of fencing off areas where banks would avoid investments based<br />

on community demographics. During the heyday of redlining, the areas most frequently<br />

discriminated against were black inner city neighborhoods. For example, in Atlanta in<br />

the 1980s, a Pulitzer Prize-winning series of articles by investigative reporter Bill<br />

Dedman showed that banks would often lend to lower-income whites but not to middleincome<br />

or upper-income blacks. The use of blacklists is a related mechanism also used<br />

by redliners to keep track of groups, areas, and people that the discriminating party<br />

feels should be denied business or aid or other transactions. In the academic literature,<br />

redlining falls under the broader category of credit rationing.<br />

History<br />

Although informal discrimination and segregation had existed in the United States, the<br />

specific practice called "redlining" began with the National Housing Act of 1934, which<br />

established the Federal Housing Administration (FHA). Racial segregation and<br />

discrimination against minorities and minority communities pre-existed this policy. The<br />

implementation of this federal policy aggravated the decay of minority inner-city<br />

neighborhoods caused by the withholding of mortgage capital, and made it even more<br />

difficult for neighborhoods to attract and retain families able to purchase homes. The<br />

assumptions in redlining resulted in a large increase in residential racial segregation<br />

and urban decay in the United States.<br />

In 1935, the Federal Home Loan Bank Board (FHLBB) asked Home Owners' Loan<br />

Corporation (HOLC) to look at 239 cities and create "residential security maps" to<br />

indicate the level of security for real-estate investments in each surveyed city. On the<br />

maps, the newest areas—those considered desirable for lending purposes—were<br />

outlined in green and known as "Type A". These were typically affluent suburbs on the<br />

outskirts of cities. "Type B" neighborhoods, outlined in blue, were considered "Still<br />

Desirable", whereas older "Type C" were labeled "Declining" and outlined in yellow.<br />

"Type D" neighborhoods were outlined in red and were considered the most risky for<br />

mortgage support. These neighborhoods tended to be the older districts in the center of<br />

Page 74 of 181


cities; often they were also black neighborhoods. Urban planning historians theorize that<br />

the maps were used by private and public entities for years afterward to deny loans to<br />

people in black communities. But, recent research has indicated that the HOLC did not<br />

redline in its own lending activities and that the racist language reflected the bias of the<br />

private sector and experts hired to conduct the appraisals.<br />

Some redlined maps were also created by private organizations, such as J.M. Brewer's<br />

1934 map of Philadelphia. Private organizations created maps designed to meet the<br />

requirements of the Federal Housing Administration's underwriting manual. The lenders<br />

had to consider FHA standards if they wanted to receive FHA insurance for their loans.<br />

FHA appraisal manuals instructed banks to steer clear of areas with "inharmonious<br />

racial groups", and recommended that municipalities enact racially restrictive zoning<br />

ordinances.<br />

Following a National Housing Conference in 1973, a group of Chicago community<br />

organizations led by The Northwest Community Organization (NCO) formed National<br />

People's Action (NPA), to broaden the fight against disinvestment and mortgage<br />

redlining in neighborhoods all over the country. This organization, led by Chicago<br />

housewife Gale Cincotta and Shel Trapp, a professional community organizer, targeted<br />

The Federal Home Loan Bank Board, the governing authority over federally chartered<br />

Savings & Loan institutions (S&L) that held at that time the bulk of the country's home<br />

mortgages. NPA embarked on an effort to build a national coalition of urban community<br />

organizations to pass a national disclosure regulation or law to require banks to reveal<br />

their lending patterns.<br />

Page 75 of 181


For many years, urban community organizations had battled neighborhood decay by<br />

attacking blockbusting, forcing landlords to maintain properties, and requiring cities to<br />

board up and tear down abandoned properties. These actions addressed the short-term<br />

issues of neighborhood decline. Neighborhood leaders began to learn that these issues<br />

and conditions were symptoms of a disinvestment that was the true, though hidden,<br />

underlying cause of these problems. They changed their strategy as more data was<br />

gathered.<br />

With the help of NPA, a coalition of loosely affiliated community organizations began to<br />

form. At the Third Annual Housing Conference held in Chicago in 1974, eight hundred<br />

delegates representing 25 states and 35 cities attended. The strategy focused on the<br />

Federal Home Loan Bank Board (FHLBB), which oversaw S&L's in cities all over the<br />

country.<br />

In 1974, Chicago's Metropolitan Area Housing Association (MAHA), made up of<br />

representatives of local organizations, succeeded in having the Illinois State Legislature<br />

pass laws mandating disclosure and outlawing redlining. In Massachusetts, organizers<br />

allied with NPA confronted a unique situation. Over 90% of home mortgages were held<br />

by state-chartered savings banks. A Jamaica Plain neighborhood organization pushed<br />

the disinvestment issue into the statewide gubernatorial race. The Jamaica Plain<br />

Banking & Mortgage Committee and its citywide affiliate, The Boston Anti-redlining<br />

Coalition (BARC), won a commitment from Democratic candidate Michael S. Dukakis to<br />

order statewide disclosure through the Massachusetts State Banking Commission. After<br />

Dukakis was elected, his new Banking Commissioner ordered banks to disclose<br />

mortgage-lending patterns by ZIP code. The suspected redlining was revealed.<br />

NPA and its affiliates achieved disclosure of lending practices with the passage of The<br />

Home Mortgage Disclosure Act of 1975. The required transparency and review of loan<br />

practices began to change lending practices. NPA began to work on reinvestment in<br />

areas that had been neglected. Their support helped gain passage in 1977 of the<br />

Community Reinvestment Act.<br />

Effect<br />

According to blackpast.org contributor Brent Gaspaire:<br />

As a consequence of redlining, neighborhoods that local banks deemed unfit for<br />

investment were left underdeveloped or in disrepair. Attempts to improve these<br />

neighborhoods with even relatively small-scale business ventures were commonly<br />

obstructed by financial institutions that continued to label the underwriting as too risky or<br />

simply rejected them outright. When existing businesses collapsed, new ones were not<br />

allowed to replace them, often leaving entire blocks empty and crumbling. Consequently,<br />

Page 76 of 181


African Americans in those neighborhoods were frequently limited in their access to<br />

banking, healthcare, retail merchandise, and even groceries.<br />

Redlining paralyzed the housing market, lowered property values in certain areas and<br />

encouraged landlord abandonment. As abandonment increased, the population density<br />

became lower. Abandoned buildings served as havens for drug dealing and other illegal<br />

activity, increasing social problems and reluctance of people to invest in these areas.<br />

Because areas were redlined residents in them were unable to obtain loans to improve<br />

their homes or get loans to move to a different area. Obviously, the neighborhoods had<br />

zero investment while neighborhoods around them improved. When the GI Bill was<br />

created during World War II, veterans who once lived in redlined areas were unable to<br />

get zero interest loans to build new homes like the rest of the returning soldiers. This<br />

forced them to stay in the areas that were poor and uninvested in while the rest of<br />

America was growing and moving to the suburbs. Around the same time the GI Bill was<br />

created, the Federal Highway Act was also created. Because the areas that were<br />

redlined were so poor, many cities chose to destroy these areas to create the highways.<br />

The residents were displaced and forced to move into different uninvested<br />

neighborhoods while their homes and businesses were destroyed by the highways.<br />

A 2017 study by Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago economists found that the practice<br />

of redlining—the practice whereby banks discriminated against the inhabitants of certain<br />

Page 77 of 181


neighborhoods—had a persistent adverse impact on the neighborhoods, with redlining<br />

affecting homeownership rates, home values and credit scores in 2010. Since many<br />

African-Americans could not access conventional home loans, they had to turn to<br />

predatory lenders (who charged high interest rates). Due to lower home ownership<br />

rates, slumlords were able to rent out apartments that would otherwise be owned.mk<br />

Court System<br />

Challenges<br />

The U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development announced a $200 million<br />

settlement with Associated Bank over redlining in Chicago and Milwaukee in May 2015.<br />

The three-year HUD observation led to the complaint that the bank purposely rejected<br />

mortgage applications from black and Latino applicants. The final settlement required<br />

AB to open branches in non-white neighborhoods, just like HCSB.<br />

New York Attorney General Eric Schneiderman announced a settlement with Evans<br />

Bank for $825,000 on September 10, 2015. An investigation had uncovered the erasure<br />

of black neighborhoods from mortgage lending maps. According to Schneiderman, of<br />

the over 1,100 mortgage applications the bank received between 2009 and 2012, only<br />

four were from African Americans. Following this investigation, the Buffalo News<br />

reported that more banks could be investigated for the same reasons in the near future.<br />

The most notable examples of such DOJ and HUD settlements have focused heavily on<br />

community banks in large metropolitan areas, but banks in other regions have been the<br />

subject of such orders as well, including First United Security Bank in Thomasville,<br />

Alabama, and Community State Bank in Saginaw, Michigan.<br />

The United States Department of Justice announced a $33 million settlement with<br />

Hudson City Savings Bank, which services New Jersey, New York, and Pennsylvania,<br />

on September 24, 2015. The six-year DOJ investigation had proven that the company<br />

was intentionally avoiding granting mortgages to Latinos and African Americans and<br />

purposely avoided expanding into minority-majority communities. The Justice<br />

Department called it the "largest residential mortgage redlining settlement in its history."<br />

As a part of the settlement agreement, HCSB was forced to open branches in non-white<br />

communities.<br />

As U.S. Attorney Paul Fishman explained to Emily Badger for The Washington Post, "[i]f<br />

you lived in a majority-black or Hispanic neighborhood and you wanted to apply for a<br />

mortgage, Hudson City Savings Bank was not the place to go." The enforcement<br />

agencies cited additional evidence of discrimination Hudson City's broker selection<br />

practices, noting that the bank received 80 percent of its mortgage applications from<br />

mortgage brokers but that the brokers with whom the bank worked were not located in<br />

majority African-American and Hispanic areas.<br />

Page 78 of 181


Legislative Action<br />

In the United States, the Fair Housing Act of 1968 was passed to fight the practice.<br />

According to the Department of Housing and Urban Development "The Fair Housing Act<br />

makes it unlawful to discriminate in the terms, conditions, or privileges of sale of a<br />

dwelling because of race or national origin. The Act also makes it unlawful for any<br />

person or other entity whose business includes residential real estate-related<br />

transactions to discriminate against any person in making available such a transaction,<br />

or in the terms or conditions of such a transaction, because of race or national origin."<br />

The Office of Fair Housing and Equal Opportunity was tasked with administering and<br />

enforcing this law. Anyone who suspects that their neighborhood has been redlined is<br />

able to file a housing discrimination complaint.<br />

The Community Reinvestment Act passed by Congress in 1977 to reduce<br />

discriminatory credit practices against low-income neighborhoods further required banks<br />

to apply the same lending criteria in all communities. Although open redlining was made<br />

illegal in the 1970s through community reinvestment legislation, the practice may have<br />

continued in less overt ways. AIDS activists allege redlining of health insurance against<br />

the LGBT community in response to the AIDS crisis.<br />

Page 79 of 181


Community Organizations<br />

ShoreBank, a community-development bank in Chicago's South Shore neighborhood,<br />

was a part of the private-sector fight against redlining. Founded in 1973, ShoreBank<br />

sought to combat racist lending practices in Chicago's African-American communities by<br />

providing financial services, especially mortgage loans, to local residents. In a 1992<br />

speech, then-Presidential candidate Bill Clinton called ShoreBank "the most important<br />

bank in America."<br />

On August 20, 2010, the bank was declared insolvent, closed by regulators and most of<br />

its assets were acquired by Urban Partnership Bank.<br />

In the mid-1970s, community organizations, under the banner of the NPA, worked to<br />

fight against redlining in South Austin, Illinois. One of these organisations was SACCC<br />

(South Austin Coalition Community Council), formed to restore South Austin's<br />

neighbourhood and to fight against financial institutions accused of propagating<br />

redlining. This got the attention of insurance regulators in the Illinois Department of<br />

Insurance, as well as federal officers enforcing anti-racial discrimination laws.<br />

Brick and Mortar<br />

Current Issues<br />

Retail<br />

Retail redlining is a spatially discriminatory practice among retailers. Taxicab services<br />

and delivery food may not serve certain areas, based on their ethnic-minority<br />

composition and assumptions about business (and perceived crime), rather than data<br />

and economic criteria, such as the potential profitability of operating in those areas.<br />

Consequently, consumers in these areas are vulnerable to prices set by fewer retailers.<br />

They may be exploited by retailers who charge higher prices and/or offer them inferior<br />

goods.<br />

Online<br />

A 2012 study by the Wall Street Journal found that Staples, Home Depot, Rosetta Stone<br />

and some other online retailers displayed different prices to customers in different<br />

locations (distinct from shipping prices). Staples based discounts on proximity to<br />

competitors like OfficeMax and Office Depot. This generally resulted in higher prices for<br />

customers in more rural areas, who were on average less wealthy than customers<br />

seeing lower prices.<br />

Page 80 of 181


Liquorlining<br />

Some service providers target low-income neighborhoods for nuisance sales. When<br />

those services are believed to have adverse effects on a community, they may<br />

considered to be a form of "reverse redlining." The term "liquorlining" is sometimes used<br />

to describe high densities of liquor stores in low income and/or minority communities<br />

relative to surrounding areas. High densities of liquor stores are associated with crime<br />

and public health issues, which may in turn drive away supermarkets, grocery stores,<br />

and other retail outlets, contributing to low levels of economic development. Controlled<br />

for income, nonwhites face higher concentrations of liquor stores than do whites.<br />

Financial Services<br />

Student Loans<br />

In December 2007, a class action lawsuit was brought against student loan lending<br />

giant Sallie Mae in the United States District Court for the District of Connecticut. The<br />

class alleged that Sallie Mae discriminated against African American and Hispanic<br />

private student loan applicants.<br />

The case alleged that the factors Sallie Mae used to underwrite private student loans<br />

caused a disparate impact on students attending schools with higher minority<br />

Page 81 of 181


populations. The suit also alleged that Sallie Mae failed to properly disclose loan terms<br />

to private student loan borrowers.<br />

The lawsuit was settled in 2011. The terms of the settlement included Sallie Mae<br />

agreeing to make a $500,000 donation to the United Negro College Fund and the<br />

attorneys for the plaintiffs receiving $1.8 million in attorneys' fees.<br />

Credit Cards<br />

Credit card redlining is a spatially discriminatory practice among credit card issuers, of<br />

providing different amounts of credit to different areas, based on their ethnic-minority<br />

composition, rather than on economic criteria, such as the potential profitability of<br />

operating in those areas. Scholars assess certain policies, such as credit card issuers<br />

reducing credit lines of individuals with a record of purchases at retailers frequented by<br />

so-called "high-risk" customers, to be akin to redlining.<br />

Insurance<br />

Gregory D. Squires wrote in 2003 that data showed that race continues to affect the<br />

policies and practices of the insurance industry. Racial profiling or redlining has a long<br />

history in the property-insurance industry in the United States. From a review of industry<br />

underwriting and marketing materials, court documents, and research by government<br />

agencies, industry and community groups, and academics, it is clear that race has long<br />

affected and continues to affect the policies and practices of the insurance industry.<br />

Home-insurance agents may try to assess the ethnicity of a potential customer just by<br />

telephone, affecting what services they offer to inquiries about purchasing a home<br />

insurance policy.<br />

This type of discrimination is called linguistic profiling. There have also been concerns<br />

raised about redlining in the automotive insurance industry. Reviews of insurance<br />

scores based on credit are shown to have unequal results by ethnic group. The Ohio<br />

Department of Insurance in the early 21st century allows insurance providers to use<br />

maps and collection of demographic data by ZIP code in determining insurance rates.<br />

The FHEO Director of Investigations at the Department of Housing and Urban<br />

Development, Sara Pratt, wrote:<br />

Like other forms of discrimination, the history of insurance redlining began in conscious,<br />

overt racial discrimination practiced openly and with significant community support in<br />

communities throughout the country. There was documented overt discrimination in<br />

practices relating to residential housing—from the appraisal manuals which established<br />

an articulated "policy" of preferences based on race, religion and national origin. to<br />

lending practices which only made loans available in certain parts of town or to certain<br />

borrowers, to the decision-making process in loans and insurance which allowed the<br />

insertion of discriminatory assessments into final decisions about either.<br />

Page 82 of 181


Mortgages<br />

Reverse Redlining occurs when a lender or insurer particularly targets minority<br />

consumers, not to deny them loans or insurance, but to charge them more than would<br />

be charged to a similarly situated white consumer, specifically marketing the most<br />

expensive and onerous loan products. These communities had largely been ignored by<br />

most lenders just a couple of decades earlier. In the 2000s some financial institutions<br />

considered black communities as suitable for subprime mortgages. Wells Fargo<br />

partnered with churches in black communities, where the pastor would deliver "wealth<br />

building" seminars in their sermons, and the bank would make a donation to the church<br />

in return for every new mortgage application. Working-class blacks wanted a part of the<br />

nation's home-owning trend. Instead of contributing to homeownership and community<br />

progress, predatory lending practices through reverse redlining stripped the equity<br />

homeowners struggled to build and drained the wealth of those communities for the<br />

enrichment of financial firms. The growth of subprime lending (higher cost loans to<br />

borrowers with flaws on their credit records) prior to the 2008 financial crisis, coupled<br />

with growing law enforcement activity in those areas, clearly showed a surge in a range<br />

of manipulative practices. Not all subprime loans were predatory, but virtually all<br />

predatory loans were subprime. Some subprime loans certainly benefit high-risk<br />

borrowers who would not qualify for conventional, prime loans. <strong>Predatory</strong> loans,<br />

however, charge unreasonably higher rates and fees by compared to the risk, trapping<br />

homeowners in unaffordable debt and often costing them their homes and life savings.<br />

Page 83 of 181


A survey of two districts of similar incomes, one being largely white and the other largely<br />

black, found that bank branches in the black community offered largely subprime loans<br />

and almost no prime loans. Studies found out that high-income blacks were almost<br />

twice as likely to end up with subprime home-purchase mortgages as did low-income<br />

whites. Some loan officers referred to blacks as "mud people" and to subprime lending<br />

as "ghetto loans." A lower savings rate and a distrust of banks, stemming from a legacy<br />

of redlining, may help explain why there are fewer branches in minority neighborhoods.<br />

In the early 21st century, brokers and telemarketers actively pushed subprime<br />

mortgages. A majority of the loans were refinance transactions, allowing homeowners to<br />

take cash out of their appreciating property or pay off credit card and other debt.<br />

Redlining has helped preserve segregated living patterns for blacks and whites in the<br />

United States, as discrimination is often contingent on the racial composition of<br />

neighborhoods and the race of the applicant. <strong>Lending</strong> institutions such as Wells Fargo<br />

have been shown to treat black mortgage applicants differently when they are buying<br />

homes in white neighborhoods than when buying homes in black neighborhoods.<br />

Dan Immergluck writes that in 2002 small businesses in black neighborhoods received<br />

fewer loans, even after accounting for business density, business size, industrial mix,<br />

neighborhood income, and the credit quality of local businesses.<br />

Several state attorneys general have begun investigating these practices, which may<br />

violate fair lending laws. The NAACP filed a class-action lawsuit charging systematic<br />

racial discrimination by more than a dozen banks.<br />

Environmental racism<br />

Policies related to redlining and urban decay can also act as a form of environmental<br />

racism, which in turn affect public health. Urban minority communities may face<br />

environmental racism in the form of parks that are smaller, less accessible and of<br />

poorer quality than those in more affluent or white areas in some cities. This may have<br />

an indirect effect on health, since young people have fewer places to play, and adults<br />

have fewer opportunities for exercise.<br />

Robert Wallace writes that the pattern of the AIDS outbreak during the 80s was affected<br />

by the outcomes of a program of "planned shrinkage" directed at African-American and<br />

Hispanic communities. It was implemented through systematic denial of municipal<br />

services, particularly fire protection resources, essential to maintain urban levels of<br />

population density and ensure community stability. Institutionalized racism affects<br />

general health care as well as the quality of AIDS health intervention and services in<br />

minority communities. The over-representation of minorities in various disease<br />

categories, including AIDS, is partially related to environmental racism. The national<br />

response to the AIDS epidemic in minority communities was slow during the 80s and<br />

Page 84 of 181


90s, showing an insensitivity to ethnic diversity in prevention efforts and AIDS health<br />

services.<br />

Workforce<br />

Workers living in American inner cities have more difficulty finding jobs than do<br />

suburban workers.<br />

Fair Housing Act<br />

Combating Redlining<br />

The Fair Housing Act (also known as the Civil Rights Act) of 1968 was passed in order<br />

to help protect minority individuals from the discriminatory practices of financial<br />

institutions and agents.<br />

Guidelines<br />

The Human Relations Commissions of Pennsylvania adopted guidelines regarding<br />

redlining. The guidelines demonstrate practices that are to be prohibited in the selling of<br />

property to people.<br />

Culture<br />

Page 85 of 181


The film Revolution '67 examines the practice of redlining that occurred in Newark, New<br />

Jersey in the 1960s.<br />

Page 86 of 181


III. Aprophobia and<br />

Economic Discrimination<br />

The Aporophobia (from the Spanish aporofobia, and this from the Ancient Greek<br />

άπορος (á-poros), without resources, indigent, poor, and φόβος (phobos), fear) refers to<br />

the fear towards poverty and towards the poor people. It is the disgust and hostility<br />

towards poor people, without resources or helpless.<br />

The concept of aporophobia was coined in the 1990s by the philosopher Adela Cortina,<br />

professor of Ethics and Political Philosophy at the University of Valencia, to differentiate<br />

this attitude from xenophobia, which only refers to the rejection of foreigners and<br />

racism, which is discrimination by ethnic groups. The difference between aporophobia<br />

and xenophobia or racism is that socially there is no discrimination or marginalization of<br />

immigrants or members of other ethnic groups when these people have assets,<br />

economic resources and/or social and media relevance.<br />

The aporophobia consists, therefore, in a feeling of fear and in an attitude of rejection of<br />

the poor, the lack of means, the helpless. Such feeling and such attitude are acquired.<br />

________<br />

Page 87 of 181


Economic Discrimination is discrimination based on economic factors. These<br />

factors can include job availability, wages, the prices and/or availability of goods and<br />

services, and the amount of capital investment funding available to minorities for<br />

business. This can include discrimination against workers, consumers, and minorityowned<br />

businesses.<br />

It is not the same as price discrimination, the practice by which monopolists (and to a<br />

lesser extent oligopolists and monopolistic competitors) charge different buyers different<br />

prices based on their willingness to pay.<br />

History<br />

A recognition of economic discrimination began in the British Railway Clauses<br />

Consolidation Act of 1845, which prohibited a common carrier from charging one person<br />

more for carrying freight than was charged to another customer for the same service. In<br />

nineteenth-century English and American common law, discrimination was<br />

characterized as improper distinctions in economic transactions; in addition to the above<br />

issue in the British Railway Clauses, a hotelier capriciously refusing to give rooms to a<br />

particular patron would constitute economic discrimination. These early laws were<br />

designed to protect discrimination from Protestants who might discriminate against<br />

Catholics or Christians who might discriminate against Jews.<br />

By the early twentieth century, economic discrimination was broadened to include<br />

biased or unequal terms against other companies or competing companies. The<br />

Robinson-Patman Act (1936), which prevents sellers of commodities in interstate<br />

commerce from discriminating in price between purchasers of goods of like grade and<br />

quality, was designed to prevent vertically integrated trusts from driving smaller<br />

competitors out of the market through economies of scale.<br />

It was not until 1941, when President Franklin D. Roosevelt issued an executive order<br />

forbidding discrimination in employment by a company working under a government<br />

defense contract, that economic discrimination took on the overtones it has today, which<br />

is discrimination against minorities. By 1960, anti-trust laws and interstate commerce<br />

laws had effectively regulated inter-corporate discrimination so problematic in the late<br />

nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, but the problem of discrimination on an<br />

economic basis against minorities had become widespread.<br />

Causes<br />

There is a wide range of theory concerned with the root causes of economic<br />

discrimination. Economic discrimination is unique from most other kinds of<br />

discrimination because only a small portion of it is due to racism, but rather is due to<br />

what has been called a "cynical realization that minorities are not always your best<br />

customers". There are three main causes that most economic theorists agree are likely<br />

root causes.<br />

Page 88 of 181


Animosity<br />

Racism, sexism, ageism, and dislike for another's religion, ethnicity or nationality has<br />

always been a component of economic discrimination, much like all other forms of<br />

discrimination.<br />

Most discrimination in the US and Europe is claimed to be in terms of racial and ethnic<br />

discrimination—mostly blacks and Hispanics in the USA, Muslims in Europe. In most<br />

parts of the world, women are held to lower positions, lower pay, and restricted<br />

opportunities of land ownership or economic incentive to enter businesses or start them.<br />

This form of economic discrimination is usually leveled at whatever groups are held to<br />

be "in power" at the time. For example, in America, discrimination is often considered to<br />

be the province of Caucasians, while in Saudi Arabia, it's men who are considered<br />

discriminatory. One study suggests that the increase in equal opportunity lawsuits has<br />

reduced this kind of discrimination in America by a large amount.<br />

Cost/Revenue<br />

There is a certain opportunity cost in dealing with some minorities, particularly in highly<br />

divided nations or nations where discrimination is tolerated.<br />

A second common reason for this kind of discrimination is when the worker or consumer<br />

is not cost-efficient. For example, some stores in the US Northwest do not stock ethnic<br />

foods, despite requests for such, since they feel the cost is too high for too low a return.<br />

Additionally, the illegal immigration debate in the US has resulted in some businesses<br />

refusing to hire such workers based on the likelihood that they would be fined and<br />

litigated against.<br />

Page 89 of 181


Efficiency<br />

In some cases, minorities are discriminated against simply because it is inefficient to<br />

make a concerted effort at a fair allocation. For example, in countries where minorities<br />

make up a very small part of the population, or are on average less educated than the<br />

population average, there is rarely an attempt to focus on employment of minorities.<br />

The Equal Opportunity Employment act in the US has almost reduced this sort of<br />

rationale for discrimination to nothing, according to recent studies.<br />

The relations between economic theory, efficiency and discrimination, or "discriminatory<br />

tastes" are much more problematic.<br />

Forms<br />

There are several forms of economic discrimination. The most common form of<br />

discrimination is wage inequality, followed by unequal hiring practices. But there is also<br />

discrimination against minority consumers and minority businesses in a number of<br />

areas, and religious or ethnic discrimination in countries outside of the United States.<br />

Against Workers<br />

Most forms of discrimination against minorities involve lower wages and unequal hiring<br />

practices.<br />

Wage Discrimination<br />

Several studies have shown that, in the United States, several minority groups,<br />

including black men and women, Hispanic men and women, and white women, suffer<br />

from decreased wage earning for the same job with the same performance levels and<br />

responsibilities as white males. Numbers vary wildly from study to study, but most<br />

indicate a gap from 5 to 15% lower earnings on average, between a white male worker<br />

and a black or Hispanic man or a woman of any race with equivalent educational<br />

background and qualifications.<br />

A recent study indicated that black wages in the US have fluctuated between 70% and<br />

80% of white wages for the entire period from 1954–1999, and that wage increases for<br />

that period of time for blacks and white women increased at half the rate of that of white<br />

males. Other studies show similar patterns for Hispanics. Studies involving women<br />

found similar or even worse rates.<br />

Overseas, another study indicated that Muslims earned almost 25% less on average<br />

than whites in France, Germany, and England, while in South America, mixed-race<br />

blacks earned half of what Hispanics did in Brazil.<br />

Page 90 of 181


Most wage discrimination is masked by the fact that it tends to occur in lower-paying<br />

positions and involves minorities who may not feel empowered to file a discrimination<br />

lawsuit or complain.<br />

UK - On 10 October 2018 the Prime Minister, Theresa May, launched a three month<br />

consultation with businesses on how large businesses would have to report the pay gap<br />

between staff of different ethnicities<br />

Hiring Discrimination<br />

Hiring discrimination is similar to wage<br />

discrimination in its pattern. It typically<br />

consists of employers choosing to hire<br />

a certain race candidate over a minority<br />

candidate, or a male candidate over a<br />

female candidate, to fill a position. A<br />

study of employment patterns in the US<br />

indicated that the number of hiring<br />

discrimination cases has increased<br />

fivefold in the past 20 years. However, their percentage as a whole fraction of the<br />

workforce hirings has decreased almost as drastically. With the stiff laws against<br />

discrimination in hiring, companies are very careful in who they hire and do not hire.<br />

Even so, studies have shown that it is easier for a white male to get a job than it is for<br />

an equally qualified man of color or woman of any race. Many positions are cycled,<br />

where a company fills a position with a worker and then lays them off and hires a new<br />

person, repeating until they find someone they feel is "suitable"—which is often not a<br />

minority.<br />

While hiring discrimination is the most highly visible aspect of economic discrimination,<br />

it is often the most uncommon. Increasingly strong measures against discrimination<br />

have made hiring discrimination much more difficult for employers to engage in.<br />

However this is only the case in formal hiring arrangements, with corporations or others<br />

subject to public scrutiny and overview.<br />

Private hiring, such as apprenticeships of electricians, plumbers, carpenters, and other<br />

trades is almost entirely broken down along racial lines, with almost no women in these<br />

fields and most minorities training those of their own race.<br />

Against Consumers<br />

Most discrimination against consumers has been decreased due to stiffer laws against<br />

such practices, but still continues, both in the US and in Europe. The most common<br />

forms of such discrimination are price and service discrimination.<br />

Page 91 of 181


Discrimination Based On Price<br />

Discrimination based on price is charging different prices for goods and services to<br />

different people based on their race, ethnicity, religion, or sex. It should not be confused<br />

with the separate economic concept of price discrimination. Discrimination based on<br />

price includes, but is not limited to:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

increased costs for basic services (health care, repair, etc.)<br />

increased costs for per diem charges (such as charging one person $40 while<br />

charging another person $100 for exactly the same service provided)<br />

not offering deals, sales, rebates, etc. to minorities<br />

higher rates for insurance for minorities<br />

Most charges of discrimination based on price are difficult to verify, without significant<br />

documentation. Studies indicate that less than 10% of all discrimination based on price<br />

is actually reported to any authority or regulatory body, and much of this is through<br />

class-action lawsuits. Furthermore, while a number of monitoring services and<br />

consumer interest groups take an interest in this form of discrimination, there is very<br />

little they can do to change it. Most discrimination based on price occurs in situations<br />

without a standardized price list that can be compared against. In the cases of per diem<br />

charges, this is easily concealed as few consumers can exchange estimates and work<br />

rates, and even if they do the business in question can claim that the services provided<br />

had different baseline costs, conditions, etc.<br />

Discrimination based on price in areas where special sales and deals simply are not<br />

offered can be justified by limiting them to those with strong credit ratings or those with<br />

past business with the company in question.<br />

Services Discrimination<br />

Although price discrimination mentions services, service discrimination is when certain<br />

services are not offered at all to minorities, or are offered only inferior versions.<br />

According to at least one study, most consumer discrimination falls into this category,<br />

since it is more difficult to verify and prove. Some assertions of discrimination have<br />

included:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

offering only high-cost plans for insurance or refusal to cover minorities<br />

refusing to offer financing to minorities<br />

denial of service<br />

Page 92 of 181


Against Businesses<br />

Minority owned businesses can also experience discrimination, both from suppliers and<br />

from banks and other sources of capital financing. In the US, there are tax benefits and<br />

even public relations benefits from having minority-owned businesses, so most<br />

instances of this occur outside of the United States.<br />

Women of color are starting businesses at rates three to five times faster than all other<br />

businesses, according to an article from Babson college on "State of Businesses<br />

Owned by Women of Color" (Press release). Newswise. May 9, 2008. Retrieved 2008-<br />

05-12. However, once in business, their growth lags behind all other firms, according to<br />

the results of a multi-year study conducted by the Center for Women's Business<br />

Research in partnership with Babson College exploring the impact of race and gender<br />

on the growth of businesses owned by women who are African-American, Asian, Latina<br />

and other ethnicities.<br />

Discrete Usage Discrimination<br />

This form of discrimination covers suppliers providing substandard goods to a business,<br />

or price gouging the business on purchases and resupply orders.<br />

Capital Investment Discrimination<br />

A more significant source of perceived discrimination is in capital investment markets.<br />

Banks are often accused of not providing loans and other financial instruments for innercity<br />

minority owned businesses. Most research indicates that the banking industry as a<br />

whole is systemic in its abuse of the legal system in avoidance of "high risk" loans to<br />

Page 93 of 181


minorities, pointing out that banks cannot provide facts backing up their assertions that<br />

they deny such loans to a high failure rate.<br />

On the other hand, most financial institutions and some economists feel that all too<br />

often, banks are accused unfairly of discrimination against minority owned businesses<br />

when said business is simply not worth such a credit risk, and that no one would find<br />

such a decision discriminatory if the business were not minority owned. These charges<br />

of reverse racism or prejudicial analysis are a longstanding source of controversy in the<br />

study of economic discrimination.<br />

Global Economic Discrimination<br />

An increasing number of economists and international commerce theorists have<br />

suggested that economic discrimination goes far beyond the bounds of individuals or<br />

businesses. The largest scale forms of economic discrimination, and the widest ranging,<br />

affect entire nations or global regions. Many consider that an open world economic<br />

system (globalization), which includes world bodies such as the International Monetary<br />

Fund (IMF), World Bank, and International Bank for Reconstruction and Development<br />

(IBRD), places countries at risk by practicing explicitly discriminatory techniques such<br />

as bilateral and regional bargaining, as well as asymmetrical trade balances and the<br />

maintaining of cheap force labor. Trade policies like the North American Free Trade<br />

Agreement (NAFTA) and General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) are often<br />

regarded as financial measures serving to economically oppress third world nations.<br />

This could include:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Unfavorable terms for monetary support from world banking institutions<br />

Coercive diplomacy to supplant local, regional or national leaders in favor of<br />

those who will act as demanded by foreign investors<br />

Increased prices for supplying basic medical supplies to nations based on ethnic<br />

or religious basis<br />

Refusal of trade agreements<br />

Restrictive trade agreements<br />

Page 94 of 181


IV. Payday <strong>Lending</strong><br />

A Payday Loan (also called a payday advance, salary loan, payroll loan, small<br />

dollar loan, short term, or cash advance loan) is a small, short-term unsecured loan,<br />

"regardless of whether repayment of loans is linked to a borrower's payday." The loans<br />

are also sometimes referred to as "cash advances," though that term can also refer to<br />

cash provided against a prearranged line of credit such as a credit card. Payday<br />

advance loans rely on the consumer having previous payroll and employment records.<br />

Legislation regarding payday loans varies widely between different countries, and in<br />

federal systems, between different states or provinces.<br />

To prevent usury (unreasonable and excessive rates of interest), some jurisdictions limit<br />

the annual percentage rate (APR) that any lender, including payday lenders, can<br />

charge. Some jurisdictions outlaw payday lending entirely, and some have very few<br />

restrictions on payday lenders. In the United States, the rates of these loans used to be<br />

restricted in most states by the Uniform Small Loan Laws (USLL), with 36–40% APR<br />

generally the norm.<br />

There are many different ways to calculate annual percentage rate of a loan. Depending<br />

on which method is used, the rate calculated may differ dramatically; e.g., for a $15<br />

Page 95 of 181


charge on a $100 14-day payday loan, it could be (from the borrower's perspective)<br />

anywhere from 391% to 3,733%.<br />

Although some have noted that these loans appear to carry substantial risk to the<br />

lender, it has been shown that these loans carry no more long term risk for the lender<br />

than other forms of credit. These studies seem to be confirmed by the United States<br />

Securities and Exchange Commission filings of at least one lender, who notes a chargeoff<br />

rate of 3.2%.<br />

The Loan Process<br />

The basic loan process involves a lender providing a short-term unsecured loan to be<br />

repaid at the borrower's next payday. Typically, some verification of employment or<br />

income is involved (via pay stubs and bank statements), although according to one<br />

source, some payday lenders do not verify income or run credit checks. Individual<br />

companies and franchises have their own underwriting criteria.<br />

In the traditional retail model, borrowers visit a payday lending store and secure a small<br />

cash loan, with payment due in full at the borrower's next paycheck. The borrower<br />

writes a postdated check to the lender in the full amount of the loan plus fees. On the<br />

maturity date, the borrower is expected to return to the store to repay the loan in person.<br />

If the borrower does not repay the loan in person, the lender may redeem the check. If<br />

the account is short on funds to cover the check, the borrower may now face a bounced<br />

check fee from their bank in addition to the costs of the loan, and the loan may incur<br />

additional fees or an increased interest rate (or both) as a result of the failure to pay.<br />

In the more recent innovation of online payday loans, consumers complete the loan<br />

application online (or in some instances via fax, especially where documentation is<br />

required). The funds are then transferred by direct deposit to the borrower's account,<br />

and the loan repayment and/or the finance charge is electronically withdrawn on the<br />

borrower's next payday.<br />

User Demographics and Reasons for Borrowing<br />

According to a study by The Pew Charitable Trusts, "Most payday loan borrowers [in the<br />

United States] are white, female, and are 25 to 44 years old. However, after controlling<br />

for other characteristics, there are five groups that have higher odds of having used a<br />

payday loan: those without a four-year college degree; home renters; African<br />

Americans; those earning below $40,000 annually; and those who are separated or<br />

divorced." Most borrowers use payday loans to cover ordinary living expenses over the<br />

course of months, not unexpected emergencies over the course of weeks. The average<br />

borrower is indebted about five months of the year.<br />

This reinforces the findings of the U.S. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)<br />

study from 2011 which found black and Hispanic families, recent immigrants, and single<br />

parents were more likely to use payday loans. In addition, their reasons for using these<br />

Page 96 of 181


products were not as suggested by the payday industry for one time expenses, but to<br />

meet normal recurring obligations.<br />

Research for the Illinois Department of Financial and Professional Regulation found that<br />

a majority of Illinois payday loan borrowers earn $30,000 or less per year. Texas' Office<br />

of the Consumer Credit Commissioner collected data on 2012 payday loan usage, and<br />

found that refinances accounted for $2.01 billion in loan volume, compared with $1.08<br />

billion in initial loan volume. The report did not include information about annual<br />

indebtedness. A letter to the editor from an industry expert argued that other studies<br />

have found that consumers fare better when payday loans are available to them. Pew's<br />

reports have focused on how payday lending can be improved, but have not assessed<br />

whether consumers fare better with or without access to high-interest loans. Pew's<br />

demographic analysis was based on a random-digit-dialing (RDD) survey of 33,576<br />

people, including 1,855 payday loan borrowers.<br />

In another study, by Gregory Elliehausen, Division of Research of the Federal Reserve<br />

System and Financial Services Research Program at the George Washington University<br />

Page 97 of 181


School of Business, 41% earn between $25,000 and $50,000, and 39% report incomes<br />

of $40,000 or more. 18% have an income below $25,000.<br />

Criticism<br />

In the UK Sarah-Jayne Clifton of the Jubilee Debt Campaign said, “austerity, low wages,<br />

and insecure work are driving people to take on high cost debt from rip-off lenders just<br />

to put food on the table. We need the government to take urgent action, not only to rein<br />

in rip-off lenders, but also to tackle the cost of living crisis and cuts to social protection<br />

that are driving people towards the loan sharks in the first place.”<br />

Draining Money From Low-Income Communities<br />

The likelihood that a family will use a payday loan increases if they are unbanked or<br />

underbanked, or lack access to a traditional deposit bank account. In an American<br />

context the families who will use a payday loan are disproportionately either of black or<br />

Hispanic descent, recent immigrants, and/or under-educated. These individuals are<br />

least able to secure normal, lower-interest-rate forms of credit. Since payday lending<br />

operations charge higher interest-rates than traditional banks, they have the effect of<br />

depleting the assets of low-income communities. The Insight Center, a consumer<br />

advocacy group, reported in 2013 that payday lending cost U.S communities $774<br />

million a year.<br />

A report from the Federal Reserve Bank of New York concluded that, "We ... test<br />

whether payday lending fits our definition of predatory. We find that in states with higher<br />

payday loan limits, less educated households and households with uncertain income<br />

are less likely to be denied credit, but are not more likely to miss a debt payment.<br />

Absent higher delinquency, the extra credit from payday lenders does not fit our<br />

definition of predatory." The caveat to this is that with a term of under 30 days there are<br />

no payments, and the lender is more than willing to roll the loan over at the end of the<br />

period upon payment of another fee. The report goes on to note that payday loans are<br />

extremely expensive, and borrowers who take a payday loan are at a disadvantage in<br />

comparison to the lender, a reversal of the normal consumer lending information<br />

asymmetry, where the lender must underwrite the loan to assess creditworthiness.<br />

A recent law journal note summarized the justifications for regulating payday lending.<br />

The summary notes that while it is difficult to quantify the impact on specific consumers,<br />

there are external parties who are clearly affected by the decision of a borrower to get a<br />

payday loan. Most directly impacted are the holders of other low interest debt from the<br />

same borrower, which now is less likely to be paid off since the limited income is first<br />

used to pay the fee associated with the payday loan. The external costs of this product<br />

can be expanded to include the businesses that are not patronized by the cashstrapped<br />

payday customer to the children and family who are left with fewer resources<br />

than before the loan. The external costs alone, forced on people given no choice in the<br />

matter, may be enough justification for stronger regulation even assuming that the<br />

Page 98 of 181


orrower him or herself understood the full implications of the decision to seek a payday<br />

loan.<br />

Advertising Practices<br />

In May 2008, the debt charity Credit Action made a complaint to the United Kingdom<br />

Office of Fair Trading (OFT) that payday lenders were placing advertising which violated<br />

advertising regulations on the social network website Facebook. The main complaint<br />

was that the APR was either not displayed at all or not displayed prominently enough,<br />

which is clearly required by UK advertising standards.<br />

In 2016, Google announced that it would ban all ads for payday loans from its systems,<br />

defined as loans requiring repayment within 60 days or (in the US) having an APR of<br />

36% or more.<br />

Unauthorized Clone Firms<br />

In August 2015, the Financial Conduct Authority (FCA) of the United Kingdom has<br />

announced that there have been an increase of unauthorized firms, also known as<br />

'clone firms', using the name of other genuine companies to offer payday loan services.<br />

Therefore, acting as a clone of the original company, such as the case of Payday Loans<br />

Now.<br />

The FCA strongly advised to verify financial firms by using the Financial Services<br />

Register, prior to participating in any sort of monetary engagement.<br />

Page 99 of 181


Aggressive Collection Practices<br />

In US law, a payday lender can use only the same industry standard collection practices<br />

used to collect other debts, specifically standards listed under the Fair Debt Collection<br />

Practices Act (FDCPA). The FDCPA prohibits debt collectors from using abusive, unfair,<br />

and deceptive practices to collect from debtors. Such practices include calling before<br />

8 o'clock in the morning or after 9 o'clock at night, or calling debtors at work.<br />

In many cases, borrowers write a post-dated check (check with a future date) to the<br />

lender; if the borrowers don't have enough money in their account by the check's date,<br />

their check will bounce. In Texas, payday lenders are prohibited from suing a borrower<br />

for theft if the check is post-dated. One payday lender in the state instead gets their<br />

customers to write checks dated for the day the loan is given. Customers borrow money<br />

because they don't have any, so the lender accepts the check knowing that it would<br />

bounce on the check's date. If the borrower fails to pay on the due date, the lender sues<br />

the borrower for writing a hot check.<br />

Payday lenders will attempt to collect on the consumer's obligation first by simply<br />

requesting payment. If internal collection fails, some payday lenders may outsource the<br />

debt collection, or sell the debt to a third party.<br />

A small percentage of payday lenders have, in the past, threatened delinquent<br />

borrowers with criminal prosecution for check fraud. This practice is illegal in many<br />

jurisdictions and has been denounced by the Community Financial Services Association<br />

of America, the industry's trade association.<br />

Pricing Structure of Payday Loans<br />

The payday lending industry argues that conventional interest rates for lower dollar<br />

amounts and shorter terms would not be profitable. For example, a $100 one-week<br />

loan, at a 20% APR (compounded weekly) would generate only 38 cents of interest,<br />

which would fail to match loan processing costs. Research shows that, on average,<br />

payday loan prices moved upward, and that such moves were "consistent with implicit<br />

collusion facilitated by price focal points".<br />

Consumer advocates and other experts argue, however, that payday loans appear to<br />

exist in a classic market failure. In a perfect market of competing sellers and buyers<br />

seeking to trade in a rational manner, pricing fluctuates based on the capacity of the<br />

market. Payday lenders have no incentive to price their loans competitively since loans<br />

are not capable of being patented.<br />

Thus, if a lender chooses to innovate and reduce cost to borrowers in order to secure a<br />

larger share of the market the competing lenders will instantly do the same, negating<br />

the effect. For this reason, among others, all lenders in the payday marketplace charge<br />

at or very near the maximum fees and rates allowed by local law.<br />

Page 100 of 181


Industry Profitability<br />

Proponents' Stance and Counterarguments<br />

In a profitability analysis by Fordham Journal of Corporate & Financial Law, it was<br />

determined that the average profit margin from seven publicly traded payday lending<br />

companies (including pawn shops) in the U.S. was 7.63%, and for pure payday lenders<br />

it was 3.57%. These averages are less than those of other traditional lending institutions<br />

such as credit unions and banks.<br />

Comparatively the profit margin of Starbucks for the measured time period was just over<br />

9%, and comparison lenders had an average profit margin of 13.04%. These<br />

comparison lenders were mainstream companies: Capital One, GE Capital, HSBC,<br />

Money Tree, and American Express Credit.<br />

Charges Are In Line With Costs<br />

A study by the FDIC Center for Financial Research found that "operating costs are not<br />

that out of line with the size of advance fees" collected and that, after subtracting fixed<br />

operating costs and "unusually high rate of default losses," payday loans "may not<br />

necessarily yield extraordinary profits."<br />

Page 101 of 181


However, despite the tendency to characterize payday loan default rates as high,<br />

several researchers have noted that this is an artifact of the normal short term of the<br />

payday product, and that during the term of loans with longer periods there are<br />

frequently points where the borrower is in default and then becomes current again.<br />

Actual charge offs are no more frequent than with traditional forms of credit, as the<br />

majority of payday loans are rolled over into new loans repeatedly without any payment<br />

applied to the original principal.<br />

The propensity for very low default rates seems to be an incentive for investors<br />

interested in payday lenders. In the Advance America 10-k SEC filing from December<br />

2011 they note that their agreement with investors, "limits the average of actual chargeoffs<br />

incurred during each fiscal month to a maximum of 4.50% of the average amount of<br />

adjusted transaction receivables outstanding at the end of each fiscal month during the<br />

prior twelve consecutive months". They go on to note that for 2011 their average<br />

monthly receivables were $287.1 million and their average charge-off was $9.3 million,<br />

or 3.2%. In comparison with traditional lenders, payday firms also save on costs by not<br />

engaging in traditional forms of underwriting, relying on their easy rollover terms and the<br />

small size of each individual loan as method of diversification eliminating the need for<br />

verifying each borrower's ability to repay. It is perhaps due to this that payday lenders<br />

rarely exhibit any real effort to verify that the borrower will be able to pay the principal on<br />

their payday in addition to their other debt obligations.<br />

Markets Provide Services Otherwise Unavailable<br />

Proponents of minimal regulations for payday loan businesses argue that some<br />

individuals that require the use of payday loans have already exhausted other<br />

alternatives. Such consumers could potentially be forced to illegal sources if not for<br />

payday loans. Tom Lehman, an advocate of payday lending, said:<br />

"... payday lending services extend small amounts of uncollateralized credit to high-risk<br />

borrowers, and provide loans to poor households when other financial institutions will<br />

not. Throughout the past decade, this "democratization of credit" has made small loans<br />

available to mass sectors of the population, and particularly the poor, that would not<br />

have had access to credit of any kind in the past."<br />

These arguments are countered in two ways. First, the history of borrowers turning to<br />

illegal or dangerous sources of credit seems to have little basis in fact according to<br />

Robert Mayer's 2012 "Loan Sharks, Interest-Rate Caps, and Deregulation". Outside of<br />

specific contexts, interest rates caps had the effect of allowing small loans in most areas<br />

without an increase of "loan sharking". Next, since 80% of payday borrowers will roll<br />

their loan over at least one time because their income prevents them from paying the<br />

principal within the repayment period, they often report turning to friends or family<br />

members to help repay the loan according to a 2012 report from the Center for<br />

Financial Services Innovation. In addition, there appears to be no evidence of unmet<br />

demand for small dollar credit in states which prohibit or strictly limit payday lending.<br />

Page 102 of 181


A 2012 report produced by the Cato Institute found that the cost of the loans is<br />

overstated, and that payday lenders offer a product traditional lenders simply refuse to<br />

offer. However, the report is based on 40 survey responses collected at a payday<br />

storefront location. The report's author, Victor Stango, was on the board of the<br />

Consumer Credit Research Foundation (CCRF) until 2015, an organization funded by<br />

payday lenders, and received $18,000 in payments from CCRF in 2013.<br />

Household Welfare Increased<br />

A staff report released by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York concluded that<br />

payday loans should not be categorized as "predatory" since they may improve<br />

household welfare. "Defining and Detecting <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong>" reports "if payday<br />

lenders raise household welfare by relaxing credit constraints, anti-predatory legislation<br />

may lower it." The author of the report, Donald P. Morgan, defined predatory lending as<br />

"a welfare reducing provision of credit." However, he also noted that the loans are very<br />

expensive, and that they are likely to be made to under-educated households or<br />

households of uncertain income.<br />

Brian Melzer of the Kellogg School of Management at Northwestern University found<br />

that payday loan users did suffer a reduction in their household financial situation, as<br />

the high costs of repeated rollover loans impacted their ability to pay recurring bills such<br />

as utilities and rent. This assumes a payday user will rollover their loan rather than<br />

Page 103 of 181


epay it, which has been shown both by the FDIC and the Consumer Finance Protection<br />

bureau in large sample studies of payday consumers.<br />

Petru Stelian Stoianovici, a researcher from Charles River Associates, and Michael T.<br />

Maloney, an economics professor from Clemson University, found "no empirical<br />

evidence that payday lending leads to more bankruptcy filings, which casts doubt on the<br />

debt trap argument against payday lending."<br />

The report was reinforced by a Federal Reserve Board (FRB) 2014 study which found<br />

that while bankruptcies did double among users of payday loans, the increase was too<br />

small to be considered significant. The same FRB researchers found that payday usage<br />

had no positive or negative impact on household welfare as measured by credit score<br />

changes over time.<br />

Aid In Disaster Areas<br />

A 2009 study by University of Chicago Booth School of Business Professor Adair Morse<br />

found that in natural disaster areas where payday loans were readily available<br />

consumers fared better than those in disaster zones where payday lending was not<br />

present. Not only were fewer foreclosures recorded, but such categories as birth rate<br />

were not affected adversely by comparison. Moreover, Morse's study found that fewer<br />

people in areas served by payday lenders were treated for drug and alcohol addiction.<br />

Australia<br />

Country Specific<br />

Prior to 2009 regulation of consumer credit was primarily conducted by the states and<br />

territories. Some states such as New South Wales and Queensland legislated effective<br />

annual interest rate caps of 48%. In 2008 the Australian states and territories referred<br />

powers of consumer credit to the Commonwealth. In 2009 the National Consumer<br />

Credit Protection Act 2009 (Cth) was introduced, which initially treated payday lenders<br />

no differently from all other lenders. In 2013 Parliament tightened regulation on the<br />

payday lending further introducing the Consumer Credit and Corporations Legislation<br />

Amendment (Enhancements) Act 2012 (Cth) which imposed an effective APR cap of<br />

48% for all consumer credit contracts (inclusive of all fees and charges). Payday<br />

lenders who provided a loan falling within the definition of a small amount credit contract<br />

(SACC), defined as a contract provided by a non authorised-deposit taking institution for<br />

less than $2,000 for a term between 16 days and 1 year, are permitted to charge a 20%<br />

establishment fee in addition to monthly (or part thereof) fee of 4% (effective 48% p.a.).<br />

Payday lenders who provide a loan falling within the definition of a medium amount<br />

credit contract (MACC), defined as a credit contract provided by a non-deposit taking<br />

institution for between $2,000–$5,000 may charge a $400 establishment fee in addition<br />

to the statutory interest rate cap of 48%. Payday lenders are still required to comply with<br />

Responsible lending obligations applying to all creditors. Unlike other jurisdictions<br />

Page 104 of 181


Australian payday lenders providing SACC or MACC products are not required to<br />

display their fees as an effective annual interest rate percentage.<br />

Canada<br />

Bill C28 supersedes the Criminal Code of Canada for the purpose of exempting Payday<br />

loan companies from the law, if the provinces passed legislation to govern payday<br />

loans. Payday loans in Canada are governed by the individual provinces. All provinces,<br />

except Newfoundland and Labrador, have passed legislation. For example, in Ontario<br />

loans have a maximum rate of 14,299% Effective Annual Rate ("EAR")($21 per $100,<br />

over 2 weeks). As of 2017, major payday lenders have reduced the rate to $18 per<br />

$100, over 2 weeks.<br />

UK<br />

The Financial Conduct Authority (FCA) estimates that there are more than 50,000 credit<br />

firms that come under its widened remit, of which 200 are payday lenders. Payday loans<br />

in the United Kingdom are a rapidly growing industry, with four times as many people<br />

using such loans in 2009 compared to 2006 – in 2009 1.2 million people took out 4.1<br />

million loans, with total lending amounting to £1.2 billion. In 2012, it is estimated that the<br />

market was worth £2.2 billion and that the average loan size was around £270. Twothirds<br />

of borrowers have annual incomes below £25,000. There are no restrictions on<br />

the interest rates payday loan companies can charge, although they are required by law<br />

to state the effective annual percentage rate (APR). In the early 2010s there was much<br />

criticism in Parliament of payday lenders.<br />

In 2014 several firms were reprimanded and required to pay compensation for illegal<br />

practices; Wonga.com for using letters untruthfully purporting to be from solicitors to<br />

Page 105 of 181


demand payment—a formal police investigation for fraud was being considered in<br />

2014—and Cash Genie, owned by multinational EZCorp, for a string of problems with<br />

the way it had imposed charges and collected money from borrowers who were in<br />

arrears.<br />

Changes In The UK Law<br />

On 1 April 2014 there was a major overhaul in the way payday loans are issued and<br />

repaid.<br />

First of all the FCA will be making sure all lenders can abide by two main goals;<br />

<br />

<br />

"to ensure that firms only lend to borrowers who can afford it", and<br />

"to increase borrowers' awareness of the cost and risk of borrowing unaffordably<br />

and ways to help if they have financial difficulties".<br />

On top of the main goals Martin Wheatley, the FCA’s chief executive officer, said:<br />

“For the many people that struggle to repay their payday loans every year this is a giant<br />

leap forward. From January next year, if you borrow £100 for 30 days and pay back on<br />

time, you will not pay more than £24 in fees and charges and someone taking the same<br />

loan for fourteen days will pay no more than £11.20. That’s a significant saving.<br />

"For those who struggle with their repayments, we are ensuring that someone borrowing<br />

£100 will never pay back more than £200 in any circumstance.<br />

"There have been many strong and competing views to take into account, but I am<br />

confident we have found the right balance.<br />

"Alongside our other new rules for payday firms – affordability tests and limits on<br />

rollovers and continuous payment authorities – the cap will help drive up standards in a<br />

sector that badly needs to improve how it treats its customers.”<br />

In order to achieve these goals the FCA has proposed the following:<br />

<br />

<br />

Initial cost cap of 0.8% per day,<br />

Fixed default fees capped at £15, and<br />

Total cost cap of 100%.<br />

United States<br />

Payday loans are legal in 27 states, and 9 others allows some form of short term<br />

storefront lending with restrictions. The remaining 14 and the District of Columbia forbid<br />

Page 106 of 181


the practice. The annual percentage rate (APR) is also limited in some jurisdictions to<br />

prevent usury. And in some states, there are laws limiting the number of loans a<br />

borrower can take at a single time.<br />

As for federal regulation, the Dodd–Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection<br />

Act gave the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) specific authority to<br />

regulate all payday lenders, regardless of size. Also, the Military <strong>Lending</strong> Act imposes a<br />

36% rate cap on tax refund loans and certain payday and auto title loans made to active<br />

duty armed forces members and their covered dependents, and prohibits certain terms<br />

in such loans.<br />

The CFPB has issued several enforcement actions against payday lenders for reasons<br />

such as violating the prohibition on lending to military members and aggressive<br />

collection tactics. The CFPB also operates a website to answer questions about payday<br />

lending. In addition, some states have aggressively pursued lenders they felt violate<br />

their state laws.<br />

Payday lenders have made effective use of the sovereign status of Native American<br />

reservations, often forming partnerships with members of a tribe to offer loans over the<br />

Internet which evade state law. However, the Federal Trade Commission has begun the<br />

aggressively monitor these lenders as well. While some tribal lenders are operated by<br />

Native Americans, there is also evidence many are simply a creation of so-called "renta-tribe"<br />

schemes, where a non-Native company sets up operations on tribal land.<br />

Page 107 of 181


Alternatives to Payday Loans<br />

Variations and Alternatives<br />

Other options are available to most payday loan customers. These include<br />

pawnbrokers, credit union loans with lower interest and more stringent terms which take<br />

longer to gain approval, employee access to earned but unpaid wages, credit payment<br />

plans, paycheck cash advances from employers ("advance on salary"), auto pawn<br />

loans, bank overdraft protection, cash advances from credit cards, emergency<br />

community assistance plans, small consumer loans, installment loans and direct loans<br />

from family or friends. The Pew Charitable Trusts found in 2013 their study on the ways<br />

in which users pay off payday loans that borrowers often took a payday loan to avoid<br />

one of these alternatives, only to turn to one of them to pay off the payday loan.<br />

If the consumer owns their own vehicle, an auto title loan would be an alternative for a<br />

payday loan, as auto title loans use the equity of the vehicle as the credit instead of<br />

payment history and employment history.<br />

Other alternatives include the Pentagon Federal Credit Union Foundation (PenFed<br />

Foundation) Asset Recovery Kit (ARK) program.<br />

Basic banking services are also often provided through their postal systems.<br />

Comparisons Payday Lenders Make<br />

Payday lenders do not compare their interest rates to those of mainstream lenders.<br />

Instead, they compare their fees to the overdraft, late payment, penalty fees and other<br />

fees that will be incurred if the customer is unable to secure any credit whatsoever.<br />

The lenders may list a different set of alternatives (with costs expressed as APRs for<br />

two-week terms, even though these alternatives do not compound their interest or have<br />

longer terms):<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

$100 payday advance with a $15 fee = 391% APR<br />

$100 bounced check with $54 NSF/merchant fees = 1,409% APR<br />

$100 credit card balance with a $37 late fee = 965% APR<br />

$100 utility bill with $46 late/reconnect fees = 1,203% APR<br />

Variations on Payday <strong>Lending</strong><br />

A minority of mainstream banks and TxtLoan companies lending short-term credit over<br />

mobile phone text messaging offer virtual credit advances for customers whose<br />

paychecks or other funds are deposited electronically into their accounts. The terms are<br />

Page 108 of 181


similar to those of a payday loan; a customer receives a predetermined cash credit<br />

available for immediate withdrawal. The amount is deducted, along with a fee, usually<br />

about 10 percent of the amount borrowed, when the next direct deposit is posted to the<br />

customer's account. After the programs attracted regulatory attention, Wells Fargo<br />

called its fee "voluntary" and offered to waive it for any reason. It later scaled back the<br />

program in several states. Wells Fargo currently offers its version of a payday loan,<br />

called "Direct Deposit Advance," which charges 120% APR. Similarly, the BBC reported<br />

in 2010 that controversial TxtLoan charges 10% for 7-days advance which is available<br />

for approved customers instantly over a text message.<br />

Income tax refund anticipation loans are not technically payday loans (because they are<br />

repayable upon receipt of the borrower's income tax refund, not at his next payday), but<br />

they have similar credit and cost characteristics. A car title loan is secured by the<br />

borrower's car, but are available only to borrowers who hold clear title (i.e., no other<br />

loans) to a vehicle. The maximum amount of the loan is some fraction of the resale<br />

value of the car. A similar credit facility seen in the UK is a logbook loan secured against<br />

a car's logbook, which the lender retains. These loans may be available on slightly<br />

better terms than an unsecured payday loan, since they are less risky to the lender. If<br />

the borrower defaults, then the lender can attempt to recover costs by repossessing and<br />

reselling the car.<br />

Postal Banking<br />

Many countries offer basic banking services through their postal systems. The United<br />

States Post Office Department offered such as service in the past. Called the United<br />

Page 109 of 181


States Postal Savings System it was discontinued in 1967. In January 2014 the Office<br />

of the Inspector General of the United States Postal Service issued a white paper<br />

suggesting that the USPS could offer banking services, to include small dollar loans for<br />

under 30% APR. Support and criticism quickly followed; opponents of postal banking<br />

argued that as payday lenders would be forced out of business due to competition, the<br />

plan is nothing more than a scheme to support postal employees.<br />

Page 110 of 181


V. Refund Anticipation <strong>Lending</strong><br />

Refund anticipation loan (RAL) is a short-term consumer loan in the United States<br />

provided by a third party against an expected tax refund for the duration it takes the tax<br />

authority to pay the refund. The loan term was usually about two to three weeks, related<br />

to the time it took the U.S. Internal Revenue Service to deposit refunds in electronic<br />

accounts. The loans were designed to make the refund available in as little as 24 hours.<br />

They were secured by a taxpayer's expected tax refund, and designed to offer<br />

customers quicker access to funds.<br />

The costs to the borrower could be significant compared to other lending and some<br />

consumer organizations warned consumers of the risk involved in this type of loan.<br />

They are a largely discontinued financial product and beginning with the 2013 tax filing<br />

season, they have been largely replaced with the similar refund anticipation checks<br />

(RAC), as well as a hodge podge of other financial products.<br />

RACs are temporary accounts which wait for the client's IRS tax refund, and which also<br />

provides a way for the client to pay for tax preparation out of the refund. Both financial<br />

products have similar fees and similar risks of third-party bank "cross-collection".<br />

A similar process in Canada to a RAL is termed "tax rebate discounting".<br />

United States<br />

In the United States prior to the 2013 tax filing season, taxpayers could apply for a<br />

refund anticipation loan through a paid professional tax preparation service, where a fee<br />

is typically charged for the preparation of the tax return. Internal Revenue Service rules<br />

Page 111 of 181


prohibit basing this fee on the amount of the expected refund. An additional fee was<br />

usually charged for the services of originating a bank product and establishing a shortterm<br />

bank account. By law this fee must be the same on both loan and non-loan bank<br />

products, and in 2004 the average fee was $32. The bank through which the loan was<br />

made charges finance charges.<br />

According to the National Consumer Law Center, 12 million taxpayers used a RAL in<br />

2004. With e-filing and IRS partnerships that help consumers e-file for free, U.S.<br />

taxpayers can generally receive their tax refunds within three weeks and sometimes as<br />

quickly as ten to fourteen days if they choose to receive their refund via direct deposit.<br />

As of 2017, 70% of US taxpayers have access to free e-file and tax preparation<br />

services. This rendered RALs less attractive to some.<br />

History<br />

RALs began in 1985 when Ronald Smith, an Accountant in Virginia Beach, VA started<br />

the practice of Refund Advance Loans at his accounting firm, Action Accounting &<br />

Taxes located at 5441 Virginia Beach Blvd. This service of Loans On Tax Refunds was<br />

advertised widely through WYAH, TV and on Cox Cable in the Hampton Roads area by<br />

Action Accounting & Taxes in 1985, 1986 and 1987. The Advance Refund Loans<br />

became a huge business success from the start and a sensation in the area in 1986<br />

and 1987 and was the first and only firm in the United States that was offering that<br />

service according to the IRS. In 1986 a salesman from Charlie Falk's Auto on Virginia<br />

Beach Blvd, where today Town Centre now exits, asked Mr. Smith if they could make<br />

an arrangement where Action Accounting & Taxes could prepare taxes for customers<br />

seeking to purchase cars in order to supplement their down payments on used or new<br />

car purchases. Mr. Smith agreed to this idea and that was the beginning of Loans on<br />

Tax Refunds being used in conjunction with car financing and that practice then quickly<br />

spread throughout the area and then throughout the entire United States. Mr. Smith was<br />

the first one to invent, organize and pioneer the process of Tax Refund Loans in this<br />

way and went on to make millions in this business. The financing was originally fully<br />

handled by Joel S. Coplon and Company, a small private financing company closely<br />

connected with Mr. Smith at the time. Action Accounting and Taxes, the firm that Mr.<br />

Smith owned, was one mile from where John Hewitt was just starting a new business<br />

venture. Mr. Hewitt had just recently purchased Mel Jackson's Tax Service which was a<br />

run down group of offices throughout the Hampton Road's area. Mr. Hewitt began to<br />

offer Refund Anticipation Loans in 1988 and built a national franchise out of the idea<br />

which funded and built Jackson Hewitt Tax Service. Then in 1989 H & R Block joined in<br />

the industry and it became a billion dollar industry across the United States being<br />

coopted into thousands of different accounting firms and tax practices across the United<br />

States and abroad. It was reported in 1989 that H & R Block had doubled it's business<br />

at over 4,000 locations due to the introduction of this new Refund Loan Service. It later<br />

spread to Canada as well through Liberty Tax Service and in time this company moved<br />

into the United States market as well offering the same service. The proliferation of this<br />

tax loan practice coincided with the introduction of electronic filing which IRS introduced<br />

electronic filing as a way to decrease its cost of operation. Previous to this time refunds<br />

Page 112 of 181


would take on average two to three months to come back from the IRS which is why the<br />

Loan on Tax Refund also known as Refund Anticipations Loan business flourished. In<br />

1988, Mr. Smith as well as Mr. Coplon were jointly sued by the Attorney General of<br />

Virginia in a Richmond State Court for charging usurious interest. Mr. Smith was<br />

eventually dismissed from the case and it was reported by the State's Attorney at the<br />

time that the reason for his dismissal from the case was that Mr. Smith was "not<br />

culpable".<br />

A tax preparer would, within 24 hours of submission, receive from the IRS confirmation<br />

that the submission was free of mathematical errors, and that the filer had no liens or<br />

delinquent federal student loans. This meant that there was good chance that the IRS<br />

would pay the refund within weeks, barring fraudulent income reporting. At that point the<br />

preparer would issue the filer a check for the amount of the expected refund minus a<br />

commission. In 1995, the New York Times reported that Beneficial's $30 electronic filing<br />

fee and $59 loan fee amounted to a 250 percent APR on a refund of $1,000.<br />

Exploitation of the system had begun by the early 1990s; filers misreported their income<br />

to inflate their refund. As a result of this, and also to discourage filers from this rather<br />

uneconomical offer, in 1994 the IRS stopped providing tax preparers a confirmation that<br />

a deposit would take place for a certain amount and that it would begin sending refunds<br />

directly to taxpayers instead of banks that made the loan, but not having the desired<br />

effects, the confirmations were re-instated the following year.<br />

Page 113 of 181


Controversy<br />

According to the Consumer Federation of America and the National Consumer Law<br />

Center, RALs are controversial because, like payday loans and title loans, RALs are<br />

high-profit, low-risk loans marketed toward the working poor. A 2006 study by the NCLC<br />

and the Consumer Federation of America found that "Based upon the prices for RALs in<br />

2006, a consumer can expect to pay about $100 in order to get a RAL for the average<br />

refund of about $2,150 from a commercial tax preparation chain this year".<br />

Opponents of RALs, like the National Consumer Law Center, argue that the profit<br />

motive of the lender results in RALs being issued too often to low-income individuals<br />

who are made to believe the wait for their refund is longer than it really is, who do not<br />

realize they are taking a loan, do not understand the high interest rates charged by the<br />

loan (often exceeding 100% APR until the last two tax filing seasons), and who do not<br />

actually need the funds immediately.<br />

Third-Party Cross-Collection of Bank Debt ("Previous Debt") for Both Rals and<br />

RACs<br />

As part of applying for both financial products, the client is directing his or her refund to<br />

the account-issuing bank. Cross-collection occurs in cases where the bank uses this<br />

occasion to collect debt owed another bank. As the IRS Taxpayer Advocate described<br />

the practice in 2006: "if a taxpayer owes money on a defaulted RAL to Bank A and<br />

subsequently attempts to buy another RAL from Bank B, Bank B is authorized to collect<br />

the outstanding debt from the RAL proceeds, transmit the funds to Bank A". It is<br />

somewhat unclear how broad is the type of debt for which banks cross-collect. This<br />

practice is often not adequately disclosed to the tax preparation client. As a lawsuit filing<br />

against H&R Block by the California Attorney General in February 2006 stated, "H&R<br />

Block does not adequately tell such customers about any alleged debts, or that when<br />

they sign the new RAL application, they agree to automatic debt collection—including<br />

collection on alleged RAL-related debts from other tax preparers or banks. These<br />

applications are denied, and the customer's anticipated refund is used to pay off the<br />

debt, plus a fee". Tax prep firms often vaguely refer to this practice merely as "previous<br />

debt".<br />

This risk exists even if the client is only using the RAC account for purposes of taking<br />

the tax preparation fees out of the refund.<br />

Jan. 2011: IRS Will Not Be Providing "Debt Indicator"<br />

On August 5, 2010, the IRS announced that for the upcoming 2011 tax filing season,<br />

the agency would no longer be providing preparers and associated financial institutions<br />

with the "debt indicator" (a one-letter code that discloses whether or not the taxpayer<br />

owes back taxes and whether or not the taxpayer owes federally collected obligations<br />

such as child support, student loans, etc.).<br />

Page 114 of 181


Taxpayers themselves will continue to have access to information about their refund<br />

through the "Where's My Refund?" feature at the irs.gov website.<br />

In the same news release, the IRS stated it was exploring ways to allow filers to directly<br />

split off part of the refund to pay for professional tax preparation, possibly starting in<br />

January 2012. The IRS is asking for input from filers, consumer advocates, and those in<br />

the tax preparation community regarding whether this would be cost-effective.<br />

Page 115 of 181


Jan. 2013: Major U.S. Banks Stop Offering Rals<br />

Beginning with the 2013 tax season, major U.S. banks will no longer be offering RALs.<br />

They will instead be offering the similar financial products of RACs, which are not loans<br />

but are rather temporary accounts which sit empty waiting for the client's IRS refund.<br />

Page 116 of 181


VI. Title Loans<br />

A Title Loan (also known as a car title loan) is a type of secured loan where<br />

borrowers can use their vehicle title as collateral. Borrowers who get title loans must<br />

allow a lender to place a lien on their car title, and temporarily surrender the hard copy<br />

of their vehicle title, in exchange for a loan amount. When the loan is repaid, the lien is<br />

removed and the car title is returned to its owner. If the borrower defaults on their<br />

payments then the lender is liable to repossess the vehicle and sell it to repay the<br />

borrowers’ outstanding debt.<br />

These loans are typically short-<br />

term, and tend to carry higher<br />

interest rates than other sources of credit.<br />

Lenders typically do<br />

not check the credit history<br />

of borrowers for these loans<br />

and only consider the<br />

value and<br />

condition of the<br />

vehicle<br />

that<br />

is being used<br />

to secure it.<br />

Despite the secured nature<br />

of the loan, lenders argue that the<br />

comparatively high rates of interest<br />

that they charge are necessary. As<br />

evidence for this, they<br />

point to the increased<br />

risk of default on a type of loan that is used almost exclusively by borrowers who are<br />

already experiencing financial difficulties.<br />

Most title loans can be acquired in 15 minutes or less on loan amounts as little as $100.<br />

Most other financial institutions will not loan under $1,000 to someone without any credit<br />

as they deem these not profitable and too risky. In addition to verifying the borrower's<br />

collateral, many lenders verify that the borrower is employed or has some source of<br />

regular income. The lenders do not generally consider the borrower's credit score.<br />

History<br />

Title loans first emerged in the early 1990s and opened a new market to individuals with<br />

poor credit and have grown increasingly popular, according to studies by the Center for<br />

Responsible <strong>Lending</strong> and Consumer Federation of America. They are the cousin of<br />

Page 117 of 181


unsecured loans, such as payday loans. Since borrowers use their car titles to secure<br />

the loans, there’s risk that the borrower can lose their vehicle by defaulting on their<br />

payments due to personal circumstances or high interest rates, which almost always<br />

have APR in the triple digits—what are sometimes called “balloon payments”.<br />

Alternative title lending exist in many states known as car title pawn or auto pawn as<br />

they are called. Similar to a traditional car title loan, a car title pawn uses both the car<br />

title and the physical vehicle (which is usually stored by the lender) to secure the loan<br />

much like any secured loan works, and there are the same risk and factors involved for<br />

the borrower but in most cases they will receive more cash in the transaction since the<br />

lender has both the vehicle and title in their possession.<br />

Process<br />

A borrower will seek the services of a lender either online or at a store location. In order<br />

to secure the loan the borrower will need to have certain forms of identification such as<br />

a valid government-issued ID like a driver’s license, proof of income, some form of mail<br />

to prove residency, car registration, a lien-free car title in their name, references, and<br />

car insurance, though not all states require lenders to show proof of auto insurance.<br />

The maximum amount of the loan is determined by the collateral. Typical lenders will<br />

offer up to half of the car's resale value, though some will go higher. Most lenders use<br />

Kelley Blue Book to find the resale value of vehicles. The borrower must hold clear title<br />

to the car; this means that the car must be paid in full with no liens or current financing.<br />

Most lenders will also require the borrower to have full insurance on the vehicle.<br />

Depending on the state where the lender is located, interest rates may range from 36%<br />

to well over 100%. Payment schedules vary but at the very least the borrower has to<br />

pay the interest due at each due date. At the end of the term of the loan, the full<br />

outstanding amount may be due in a single payment. If the borrower is unable to repay<br />

the loan at this time, then they can roll the balance over, and take out a new title loan.<br />

Government regulation often limits the total number of times that a borrower can roll the<br />

loan over, so that they do not remain perpetually in debt.<br />

If the borrower cannot pay back the loan or is late with his or her payments, the title loan<br />

lender may seek to take possession of the car and sell it to offset what is owed.<br />

Typically lenders choose this option as a last resort because it may take months to<br />

recover the vehicle, and repossession, auction, and court costs all decrease the amount<br />

of money they are able to recoup. During this time, the lender is not collecting payments<br />

yet the vehicle is depreciating. Most states require the title loan lender to hold the<br />

vehicle for 30 days to allow the borrower to recover it by paying the balance. Typically,<br />

any amount from the sale over the existing loan balance is returned to the defaulter.<br />

Today, the internet has revolutionized how companies can reach their clientele, and<br />

many title loan companies offer online applications for pre-approval or approval on title<br />

loans. These applications require much of the same information and still may require a<br />

Page 118 of 181


orrower to visit a store to pick up their money, usually in the form of a check. When<br />

filling out these applications, they may ask for things like the vehicle's Vehicle<br />

Identification Number (VIN) and/or insurance policy numbers.<br />

Loan Calculation<br />

The amount a borrower can be loaned is dependent on the worth of their vehicle. A<br />

lender will typically look up the auction value of the car being used as collateral and<br />

offer a loan that’s between 30% and 50% of the worth of the vehicle. This leaves<br />

lenders a cushion to make profit if ever they need to repossess the vehicle and sell it at<br />

auction, in the event the borrower defaults.<br />

States Offering<br />

Title Loans<br />

Title loans are not<br />

offered in all states.<br />

Some states have<br />

made them illegal<br />

because they are<br />

considered a welfarereducing<br />

provision of<br />

credit, or predatory<br />

lending. Other states,<br />

like Montana, have<br />

begun placing strict<br />

regulations on title<br />

loans by not allowing<br />

the APR to reach<br />

above 36%, down from the previous 400%. However, Montana has recently voted<br />

against allowing title loans in the state.<br />

In 2008, New Hampshire passed a law capping APR at 36%. Some companies claim<br />

their average loan amounts to be between $300 and $500, and had to shut down their<br />

store fronts in that state, or their business entirely, because their business could not<br />

survive on a low APR for low loan amounts. Since then, the law has been reversed and<br />

new growth in the title loan industry has emerged, allowing title loan lenders to charge<br />

25% interest a month, or roughly 300% APR.<br />

States continue to vote on legislation allowing or disallowing title loans. Some states<br />

have no limit on the APR that title loan companies can charge, while others continue to<br />

crack down and push for stricter regulation. Early in 2012, Illinois recently voted to cap<br />

APR on title loans at 36%, with other provisions that would limit the title loan industry in<br />

the state. The vote did not pass, but voters and politicians in Illinois and other states<br />

continue in their convictions to regulate or outlaw title loans.<br />

Page 119 of 181


Demographic of Small-Dollar-Credit Consumers<br />

Small-dollar-credit (SDC) refers to services offered by payday and title loan industries.<br />

In 2012, a study was conducted by the Center for Financial Services Innovation.<br />

According to the study, SDC consumers are generally less educated, have more<br />

children, and are based in the South, where there is a greater concentration of<br />

unbanked or underbanked people. In addition, there’s a healthy spread of SDC<br />

consumers with a range of salaries—showing 20% of SDC consumers have a<br />

household income between $50,000 and $75,000. However, 45% of respondents to the<br />

survey would classify themselves as “poor”.<br />

Controversy<br />

In a BBC article, a spokesman for a company offering short-term loans says that APR is<br />

not a valid model when assessing costs associated with short-term subprime loans, and<br />

that the charges are appropriate for the convenience of quickly obtaining a short-term<br />

loan. Instead, the APR model is better for assessing costs associated with a middle- or<br />

long-term loan options.<br />

The high interest rates on title loans are justified by defenders of the industry, stating<br />

that the higher interest rates are necessary for the lending companies to turn profit. The<br />

borrowers are considered "high risk" and may default on their debt. Therefore, the<br />

higher interest rates are a means of securing profit even if the borrower defaults, and<br />

ensures the company sees a positive rate of return.<br />

Criticism<br />

Critics of title loans contend that the business model seeks and traps impoverished<br />

individuals with ridiculous interest rates by lenders who aren’t entirely transparent<br />

regarding the payments. This practice lends confusion and so some borrowers are<br />

unaware of the situation that getting a small-dollar-credit loan puts them in. However,<br />

they are already locked in the loan and have no means of escaping other than paying<br />

the loan off or losing their vehicle.<br />

The practice has been compared to loan sharking, because the interest rates are so<br />

high.<br />

Even though states are placing stringent restrictions on things like interest rates that can<br />

be charged, regulating the practices of companies offering short-term loans, like payday<br />

loans or title loans, proves to be a difficult endeavor. The Consumer Financial<br />

Protection Bureau and the Federal Trade Commission, both federal regulatory agencies<br />

responsible for enforcing federal law with non-banking institutions, admit that they do<br />

not have the authority to enforce the Military <strong>Lending</strong> Act, which states that military<br />

members and their families can pay an APR no higher than 36%, while banning loans to<br />

service members that would be secured through their banking accounts, vehicles, or<br />

paychecks.<br />

Page 120 of 181


Some lenders can move around the Military <strong>Lending</strong> Act's restrictions by offering openended<br />

credit loans instead of title loans or payday loans. This allows them to continue<br />

charging triple-digit APR on their loans.<br />

Some groups, such<br />

as the Texas Fair<br />

<strong>Lending</strong> Alliance,<br />

present title loans<br />

and payday loans<br />

as a form of<br />

entrapment, where<br />

taking out one of<br />

these means that<br />

borrowers will find<br />

themselves cycling<br />

further into debt<br />

with less chances of<br />

getting out of debt<br />

when compared to<br />

not taking the loan<br />

out at all,<br />

contending that<br />

75% of payday<br />

loans are taken out<br />

within two weeks of<br />

the previous loan in<br />

order to fill the gap<br />

in finances from<br />

when the loan was<br />

originally taken out.<br />

In 2001, Texas<br />

passed a law<br />

capping interest<br />

rates on title loans<br />

and payday loans.<br />

However, lenders<br />

are getting around<br />

the restrictions by exploiting loopholes allowing them to lend for the same purposes,<br />

with high-interest rates, disguised as loan brokers or as a Credit Services Organization<br />

(CSO).<br />

The Vice President of state policy at the Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong> in Durham,<br />

North Carolina argues that the car title loan model is built around loans that are<br />

impossible to repay. He goes on to cite a 2007 study by the Center for Responsible<br />

Page 121 of 181


<strong>Lending</strong> which shows that 20% of title loan borrowers in Chicago had taken out a loan in<br />

order to repay a previous loan to the same lender.<br />

Evidence from The Pew Charitable Trusts cite a need for consumers to be better<br />

informed. The Pew report states that of the more than 2 million consumers who obtain<br />

title loans, one out of nine consumers default on their loans, and notes that<br />

repossession affects approximately 5 to 9 percent of borrowers who default.<br />

Page 122 of 181


VII. Loan Sharks<br />

A Loan Shark is a (person) who offers loans at extremely high interest rates, has<br />

cruel (or strict) terms of collection upon failure, and operates outside off the street<br />

(outside of local authority). The term usually refers to illegal activity, but may also refer<br />

to predatory lending with extremely high interest rates such as payday or title loans.<br />

An unintended consequence of poverty alleviation initiatives can be that loan sharks<br />

borrow from formal microfinance lenders and lend on to poor borrowers. Loan sharks<br />

sometimes enforce repayment by blackmail or threats of violence. Historically, many<br />

moneylenders skirted between legal and criminal activity. In the recent western world,<br />

loan sharks have been a feature of the criminal underworld.<br />

19th-Century Salary Lenders<br />

United States<br />

In late 19th-century America, the low legal interest rates made small loans unprofitable,<br />

and small-time lending was viewed as irresponsible by society. Banks and other major<br />

financial institutions thus stayed away from small-time lending. There were, however,<br />

plenty of small lenders offering loans at profitable but illegally high interest rates. They<br />

presented themselves as legitimate and operated openly out of offices. They only<br />

sought customers who had a steady and respectable job, a regular income and a<br />

reputation to protect. This made them less likely to leave the area before they paid their<br />

Page 123 of 181


debt and more likely to have a legitimate reason for borrowing money. Gamblers,<br />

criminals, and other disreputable, unreliable types were avoided. They made the<br />

borrower fill out and sign seemingly legitimate contracts. Though these contracts were<br />

not legally enforceable, they at least were proof of the loan, which the lender could use<br />

to blackmail a defaulter.<br />

To force a defaulter into paying, the lender might threaten legal action. This was a bluff,<br />

since the loan was illegal. The lender preyed on the borrower's ignorance of the law.<br />

Alternatively, the lender resorted to public shaming, exploiting the social stigma of being<br />

in debt to a loan shark. They were able to complain to the defaulter's employer, because<br />

many employers would fire employees who were mired in debt, because of the risk of<br />

them stealing from the employer to repay debts. They were able to send agents to stand<br />

outside the defaulter's home, loudly denouncing him, perhaps vandalizing his home with<br />

graffiti or notices. Whether out of gullibility or embarrassment, the borrower usually<br />

succumbed and paid.<br />

Many customers were employees of large firms, such as railways or public works.<br />

Larger organizations were more likely to fire employees for being in debt, as their rules<br />

were more impersonal, which made blackmail easier. It was easier for lenders to learn<br />

which large organizations did this as opposed to collecting information on the multitude<br />

of smaller firms. Larger firms had more job security and the greater possibility of<br />

promotion, so employees sacrificed more to ensure they were not fired. The loan shark<br />

could also bribe a large firm's paymaster to provide information on its many employees.<br />

Regular salaries and paydays made negotiating repayment plans simpler.<br />

The size of the loan and the repayment plan were often tailored to suit the borrower's<br />

means. The smaller the loan, the higher the interest rate was, as the costs of tracking<br />

and pursuing a defaulter (the overhead) were the same whatever the size of the loan.<br />

The attitudes of lenders to defaulters also varied: some were lenient and reasonable,<br />

readily granting extensions and slow to harass, while others unscrupulously tried to milk<br />

all they could from the borrower (e.g. imposing late fees).<br />

Because salary lending was a disreputable trade, the owners of these firms often hid<br />

from public view, hiring managers to run their offices indirectly. To further avoid<br />

attracting attention, when expanding his trade to other cities, an owner would often<br />

found new firms with different names rather than expanding his existing firm into a very<br />

noticeable leviathan.<br />

The penalties for being an illegal lender were mild. Illegal lending was a misdemeanor,<br />

and the penalty was forfeiture of the interest and perhaps the principal as well. But<br />

these were only ever imposed if the borrower sued, which he typically could not afford<br />

to do.<br />

Opposition to salary lenders was spearheaded by social elites, such as businessmen<br />

and charity organizations. Businessmen were encouraged not to fire employees who<br />

were indebted to loan sharks, as they unwittingly supported the industry by providing<br />

Page 124 of 181


lenders with a means of blackmailing their customers ("pay up or we'll tell your boss and<br />

you'll be fired"). Charities provided legal support to troubled borrowers. This fight<br />

culminated in the drafting of the Uniform Small Loan Law, which brought into existence<br />

a new class of licensed lender. The law was enacted, first in several states in 1917, and<br />

was adopted by all but a handful of states by the middle of the 20th century. The model<br />

statute mandated consumer protections and capped the interest rate on loans of $300<br />

or less at 3.5% a month (42% a year), a profitable level for small loans. Lenders had to<br />

give the customer copies of all signed documents. Additional charges such as late fees<br />

were banned. The lender could no longer receive power of attorney or confession of<br />

judgment over a customer. These licensing laws made it impossible for usurious lenders<br />

to pass themselves off as legal. Small loans also started becoming more socially<br />

acceptable, and banks and other larger institutions started offering them as well.<br />

20th-Century Gangsters<br />

In the 1920s and 1930s, American prosecutors began to notice the emergence of a new<br />

breed of illegal lender that used violence to enforce debts. The new small lender laws<br />

had made it almost impossible to intimidate customers with a veneer of legality, and<br />

many customers were less vulnerable to shaming because they were either selfemployed<br />

or already disreputable.<br />

Thus, violence was an important tool, though not their only one. These loan sharks<br />

operated more informally than salary lenders, which meant more discretion for the<br />

lender and less paperwork and bureaucracy for the customer. They were also willing to<br />

serve high-risk borrowers that legal lenders wouldn't touch.<br />

Page 125 of 181


Threats of violence were rarely followed through, however. One possible reason is that<br />

injuring a borrower could have meant he couldn't work and thus could never pay off his<br />

debt. Many regular borrowers realized the threats were mostly bluffs and that they could<br />

get away with delinquent payments. A more certain consequence was that the<br />

delinquent borrower would be cut off from future loans, which was serious for those who<br />

regularly relied on loan sharks.<br />

One important market for violent loan sharks was illegal gambling operators, who<br />

couldn't expose themselves to the law to collect debts legally. They cooperated with<br />

loan sharks to supply credit and collect payments from their punters. Thieves and other<br />

criminals, whose fortunes were frequently in flux, were also served, and these<br />

connections also allowed the loan sharks to operate as fences. [13] Another type of highrisk<br />

customer was the small businessman in dire financial straits who couldn't qualify for<br />

a legal loan.<br />

Violent loansharking was typically run by criminal syndicates, such as the Mafia. Many<br />

of these were former bootleggers who needed a new line of work after the end of<br />

Prohibition. Towards the 1960s, loan sharks grew ever more coordinated, and could<br />

pool information on borrowers to better size up risks and ensure a borrower did not try<br />

to pay off one loan by borrowing from another loan shark. The fearsome reputation of<br />

the Mafia or similar large gang made the loan shark's threat of violence more credible.<br />

Mafia Links<br />

Origins In "Salary Buying", 1920-Criminalization<br />

Although the reform law was intended to starve the loan sharks into extinction, this<br />

species of predatory lender thrived and evolved. After high-rate salary lending was<br />

outlawed, some bootleg vendors recast the product as "salary buying". They claimed<br />

they were not making loans but were purchasing future wages at a discount. This form<br />

of loansharking proliferated through the 1920s and into the 1930s until a new draft of<br />

the Uniform Small Loan Law closed the loophole through which the salary buyers had<br />

slipped. [14] Salary-buying loan sharks continued to operate in some southern states after<br />

World War II because the usury rate was set so low that licensed personal finance<br />

companies could not do business there.<br />

Post-Criminalization<br />

Organized crime began to enter the cash advance business in the 1930s, after high-rate<br />

lending was criminalized by the Uniform Small Loan Law. The first reports of mob<br />

loansharking surfaced in New York City in 1935, and for 15 years, underworld money<br />

lending was apparently restricted to that city. There is no record of syndicate "juice"<br />

operations in Chicago, for instance, until the 1950s.<br />

In the beginning, underworld loansharking was a small loan business, catering to the<br />

same populations served by the salary lenders and buyers. Those who turned to the<br />

Page 126 of 181


ootleg lenders could not get credit at the licensed companies because their incomes<br />

were too low or they were deemed poor risks. The firms operating within the usury cap<br />

turned away roughly half of all applicants and tended to make larger loans to married<br />

men with steady jobs and decent incomes.<br />

Those who could not get a legal loan at 36% or 42% a year could secure a cash<br />

advance from a mobster at the going rate of 10% or 20% a week for small loans. Since<br />

the mob loans were not usually secured with legal instruments, debtors pledged their<br />

bodies as collateral.<br />

In its early phase, a large fraction of mob loansharking consisted of payday lending.<br />

Many of the customers were office clerks and factory hands. The loan fund for these<br />

operations came from the proceeds of the numbers racket and was distributed by the<br />

top bosses to the lower echelon loan sharks at the rate of 1% or 2% a week. The 1952<br />

B-flick Loan Shark, starring George Raft, offers a glimpse of mob payday lending. The<br />

waterfront in Brooklyn was another site of extensive underworld payday advance<br />

operations around mid-century.<br />

1960s Heyday–Present<br />

Over time, mob loan sharks moved away from such labor intensive rackets. By the<br />

1960s, the preferred clientele was small and medium-sized businesses. Business<br />

customers had the advantage of possessing assets that could be seized in case of<br />

default, or used to engage in fraud or to launder money. Gamblers were another<br />

lucrative market, as were other criminals who needed financing for their operations. By<br />

Page 127 of 181


the 1970s, mob salary lending operations seemed to have withered away in the United<br />

States.<br />

At its height in the 1960s, underworld loansharking was estimated to be the second<br />

most lucrative franchise of organized crime in the United States after illegal gambling.<br />

Newspapers in the 1960s were filled with sensational stories of debtors beaten,<br />

harassed, and sometimes murdered by mob loan sharks. Yet careful studies of the<br />

business have raised doubts about the frequency with which violence was employed in<br />

practice. Relations between creditor and debtor could be amicable, even when the "vig"<br />

or "juice" was exorbitant, because each needed the other. FBI agents in one city<br />

interviewed 115 customers of a mob loan business but turned up only one debtor who<br />

had been threatened. None had been beaten.<br />

Non-Mafia Sharks<br />

Organized crime has never had a monopoly on black market lending. Plenty of vestpocket<br />

lenders operated outside the jurisdiction of organized crime, charging usurious<br />

rates of interest for cash advances. These informal networks of credit rarely came to the<br />

attention of the authorities but flourished in populations not served by licensed lenders.<br />

Even today, after the rise of corporate payday lending in the United States, unlicensed<br />

loan sharks continue to operate in immigrant enclaves and low-income neighborhoods.<br />

They lend money to people who work in the informal sector or who are deemed to be<br />

too risky even by the check-cashing creditors. Some beat delinquents while others seize<br />

assets instead. Their rates run from 10% to 20% a week, just like the mob loan sharks<br />

of days gone by.<br />

US Loan Sharks<br />

USA has a loan shark law, the maximum rate is set. Roman University Law was (or is)<br />

tied to usury laws for most of European legal history. Beyond that, more recently, USA<br />

has maximum rates for credit lenders and for 1st and 2nd mortgage lenders and auto<br />

loans too. In modern times it was said "you can't get a loan unless you don't need the<br />

money", however recently the legal focus has been in preventing lending by institutions<br />

who know the persons will fail to pay - a thing called "predatory lending" (which is a<br />

different topic).<br />

UK loan sharks<br />

The research by the government and other agencies estimates that 165,000 to 200,000<br />

people are indebted to loan sharks in the United Kingdom. Illicit loan sharking is treated<br />

as a high-level crime by law enforcement, due to its links to organized crime and the<br />

serious violence involved. Payday loans with high interest rates are legal in many<br />

cases, and have been described as "legal loan sharking" (in that the creditor is legally<br />

registered, pays taxes and contributions, and can reclaim remittance if taking the case<br />

to adjudication; likewise there is no threat of harm to the debtor).<br />

Page 128 of 181


Loan Sharks in Ireland<br />

The Central Bank of Ireland were criticized by for doing nothing to protect those on low<br />

incomes, the vulnerable or have low levels of financial literacy from loan sharks when it<br />

emerged that up to 100,000 of the 360,000 loans given by moneylenders broke the law.<br />

Non-Standard Lenders In The United States<br />

In the United States, there are lenders licensed to serve borrowers who cannot qualify<br />

for standard loans from mainstream sources. These smaller, non-standard lenders often<br />

operate in cash, whereas mainstream lenders increasingly operate only electronically<br />

and will not serve borrowers who do not have bank accounts. Terms such as sub-prime<br />

lending, "non-standard consumer credit", and payday loans are often used in<br />

connection with this type of consumer finance. The availability of these services has<br />

made illegal, exploitative loan sharks rarer, but these legal lenders have also been<br />

accused of behaving in an exploitative manner. For example, payday loan operations<br />

have come under fire for charging inflated "service charges" for their services of cashing<br />

a "payday advance", effectively a short-term (no more than one or two weeks) loan for<br />

which charges may run 3–5% of the principal amount. By claiming to be charging for the<br />

"service" of cashing a paycheck, instead of merely charging interest for a short-term<br />

loan, laws that strictly regulate moneylending costs can be effectively bypassed.<br />

Page 129 of 181


Payday lending<br />

Licensed payday advance businesses, which lend money at high rates of interest on the<br />

security of a postdated check, are often described as loan sharks by their critics due to<br />

high interest rates that trap debtors, stopping short of illegal lending and violent<br />

collection practices. Today's payday loan is a close cousin of the early 20th century<br />

salary loan, the product to which the "shark" epithet was originally applied, but they are<br />

now legalised in some states.<br />

A 2001 comparison of short-term lending rates charged by the Chicago Outfit organized<br />

crime syndicate and payday lenders in California revealed that, depending on when a<br />

payday loan was paid back by a borrower (generally 1–14 days), the interest rate<br />

charged for a payday loan could be considerably higher than the interest rate of a<br />

similar loan made by the organized crime syndicate.<br />

Yamikinyu in Japan<br />

The regulation of moneylenders is typically much looser than that of banks. In Japan,<br />

the Moneylending Control Law requires only registration in each prefecture. In Japan,<br />

as the decades-long depression lingers, banks are reluctant to spare money and<br />

regulation becomes tighter, illegal moneylending has become a social issue. Illegal<br />

moneylenders typically charge an interest of 30 or 50% in 10 days (in Japanese, these<br />

are called "to-san" ('to' meaning ten and 'san' meaning three) or "to-go" ('to' meaning ten<br />

and 'go' meaning five)), which is about 1.442 million % or 267.5 million % per annum.<br />

This is against the law that sets the maximum interest rate at 20%. They usually do<br />

business with those who cannot get more money from banks, legitimate consumer<br />

loans, or credit cards.<br />

Ah Long in Malaysia and Singapore<br />

Ah Long (derived from the Cantonese phrase ' 大 耳 窿 ' ("big ear hole")) is a colloquial<br />

term for illegal loan sharks in Malaysia and Singapore. They lend money to people who<br />

are unable to obtain loans from banks or other legal sources, mostly targeting habitual<br />

gamblers. Often, they discreetly advertise by sticking notices, mostly on lamp posts and<br />

utility boxes around a neighbourhood, thus vandalising public property, as authorities<br />

must remove such advertisements. They charge high interest rates (generally about<br />

40% per month/fortnight) according to Anti-Crime, Drug and Social Development<br />

Voluntary Organisation and frequently threaten violence (and administer it) towards<br />

those who fail to pay on time.<br />

Ah Long tactics<br />

When a person fails to pay on time, the Ah Long will set fire, spray paint, splash, or<br />

write threats in paint or markers on the walls of the property of that person as a threat of<br />

violence and to scare, and perhaps shame, the borrower into repaying the loan. A<br />

common use of painting includes the characters "O$P$" meaning "owe money, pay<br />

Page 130 of 181


money", as well as the debtors' unit number. According to local police authorities, there<br />

have been cases where borrowers and their family members were beaten or had their<br />

property damaged or destroyed, and some victims have committed suicide.<br />

Page 131 of 181


Page 132 of 181


VIII. Usury<br />

Usury (/ˈjuːʒəri/) is, as defined today, the practice of making unethical or immoral<br />

monetary loans that unfairly enrich the lender. Originally, usury meant interest of any<br />

kind. A loan may be considered usurious because of excessive or abusive interest rates<br />

or other factors. Historically, in some Christian societies, and in many Islamic societies<br />

even today, charging any interest at all would be considered usury. Someone who<br />

practices usury can be called a usurer, but a more common term in contemporary<br />

English is loan shark.<br />

The term may be used in a moral sense—condemning, taking advantage of others'<br />

misfortunes—or in a legal sense where interest rates may be regulated by law.<br />

Historically, some cultures (e.g., Christianity in much of Medieval Europe, and Islam in<br />

many parts of the world today) have regarded charging any interest for loans as sinful.<br />

Some of the earliest known condemnations of usury come from the Vedic texts of India.<br />

Similar condemnations are found in religious texts from Buddhism, Judaism,<br />

Christianity, and Islam (the term is riba in Arabic and ribbit in Hebrew). At times, many<br />

nations from ancient Greece to ancient Rome have outlawed loans with any interest.<br />

Though the Roman Empire eventually allowed loans with carefully restricted interest<br />

rates, the Catholic Church in medieval Europe banned the charging of interest at any<br />

rate (as well as charging a fee for the use of money, such as at a bureau de change).<br />

Page 133 of 181


Historical Meaning<br />

Banking during the Roman Empire was different from modern banking. During the<br />

Principate, most banking activities were conducted by private individuals who operated<br />

as large banking firms do today. Anybody that had any available liquid assets and<br />

wished to lend it out could easily do so.<br />

The annual rates of interest on loans varied in the range of 4–12 percent, but when the<br />

interest rate was higher, it typically was not 15–16 percent but either 24 percent or 48<br />

percent. The apparent absence of intermediate rates suggests that the Romans may<br />

have had difficulty calculating the interest on anything other than mathematically<br />

convenient rates. They quoted them on a monthly basis, and the most common rates<br />

were multiples of twelve. Monthly rates tended to range from simple fractions to 3–4<br />

percent, perhaps because lenders used Roman numerals.<br />

Moneylending during this period was largely a matter of private loans advanced to<br />

persons persistently in debt or temporarily so until harvest time. Mostly, it was<br />

undertaken by exceedingly rich men prepared to take on a high risk if the profit looked<br />

good; interest rates were fixed privately and were almost entirely unrestricted by law.<br />

Investment was always regarded as a matter of seeking personal profit, often on a large<br />

scale. Banking was of the small, back-street variety, run by the urban lower-middle<br />

class of petty shopkeepers. By the 3rd century, acute currency problems in the Empire<br />

drove such banking into decline. The rich who were in a position to take advantage of<br />

the situation became the moneylenders when the increasing tax demands in the last<br />

declining days of the Empire crippled and eventually destroyed the peasant class by<br />

reducing tenant-farmers to serfs. It was evident that usury meant exploitation of the<br />

poor.<br />

The First Council of Nicaea, in 325, forbade clergy from engaging in usury [9] (canon 17).<br />

At the time, usury was interest of any kind, and the canon forbade the clergy to lend<br />

money at interest rates even as low as 1 percent per year. Later ecumenical councils<br />

applied this regulation to the laity.<br />

Lateran III decreed that persons who accepted interest on loans could receive neither<br />

the sacraments nor Christian burial. Pope Clement V made the belief in the right to<br />

usury a heresy in 1311, and abolished all secular legislation which allowed it. Pope<br />

Sixtus V condemned the practice of charging interest as "detestable to God and man,<br />

damned by the sacred canons, and contrary to Christian charity."<br />

Theological historian John Noonan argues that "the doctrine [of usury] was enunciated<br />

by popes, expressed by three ecumenical councils, proclaimed by bishops, and taught<br />

unanimously by theologians."<br />

Page 134 of 181


Certain negative historical renditions of usury carry with them social connotations of<br />

perceived "unjust" or "discriminatory" lending practices. The historian Paul Johnson,<br />

comments:<br />

Most early religious systems in the ancient Near East, and the secular codes arising<br />

from them, did not forbid usury. These societies regarded inanimate matter as alive, like<br />

plants, animals and people, and capable of reproducing itself. Hence if you lent 'food<br />

money', or monetary tokens of any kind, it was legitimate to charge interest. Food<br />

money in the shape of olives, dates, seeds or animals was lent out as early as c. 5000<br />

BC, if not earlier. ...Among the Mesopotamians, Hittites, Phoenicians and Egyptians,<br />

interest was legal and often fixed by the state. But the Hebrew took a different view of<br />

the matter.<br />

The Hebrew Bible regulates interest taking. Interest can be charged to strangers but not<br />

between Hebrews.<br />

Deuteronomy 23:19 Thou shalt not lend upon interest to thy brother: interest of money,<br />

interest of victuals, interest of any thing that is lent upon interest.<br />

Deuteronomy 23:20 Unto a foreigner thou mayest lend upon interest; but unto thy<br />

brother thou shalt not lend upon interest; that the LORD thy God may bless thee in all<br />

that thou puttest thy hand unto, in the land whither thou goest in to possess it.<br />

Israelites were forbidden to charge interest on loans made to other Israelites, but<br />

allowed to charge interest on transactions with non-Israelites, as the latter were often<br />

amongst the Israelites for the purpose of business anyway; but in general, it was seen<br />

Page 135 of 181


as advantageous to avoid getting into debt at all, to avoid being bound to someone else.<br />

Debt was to be avoided and not used to finance consumption, but only taken on when in<br />

need; however, the laws against usury were among many laws which the prophets<br />

condemn the people for breaking.<br />

Johnson contends that the Torah treats lending as philanthropy in a poor community<br />

whose aim was collective survival, but which is not obliged to be charitable towards<br />

outsiders.<br />

A great deal of Jewish legal scholarship in the Dark and the Middle Ages was devoted<br />

to making business dealings fair, honest and efficient.<br />

Usury (in the original sense of any interest) was at times denounced by a number of<br />

religious leaders and philosophers in the ancient world, including Moses, Plato,<br />

Aristotle, Cato, Cicero, Seneca, Aquinas, Muhammad, Jesus, Philo and Gautama<br />

Buddha. For example, Cato said:<br />

"And what do you think of usury?"—"What do you think of murder?"<br />

Interest of any kind is forbidden in Islam. As such, specialized codes of banking have<br />

developed to cater to investors wishing to obey Qur'anic law. (See Islamic banking)<br />

As the Jews were ostracized from most professions by local rulers, the Western<br />

churches and the guilds, they were pushed into marginal occupations considered<br />

socially inferior, such as tax and rent collecting and moneylending. Natural tensions<br />

between creditors and debtors were added to social, political, religious, and economic<br />

strains.<br />

...financial oppression of Jews tended to occur in areas where they were most disliked,<br />

and if Jews reacted by concentrating on moneylending to non-Jews, the unpopularity—<br />

and so, of course, the pressure—would increase. Thus the Jews became an element in<br />

a vicious circle. The Christians, on the basis of the Biblical rulings, condemned interesttaking<br />

absolutely, and from 1179 those who practiced it were excommunicated. Catholic<br />

autocrats frequently imposed the harshest financial burdens on the Jews. The Jews<br />

reacted by engaging in the one business where Christian laws actually discriminated in<br />

their favor, and became identified with the hated trade of moneylending.<br />

In England, the departing Crusaders were joined by crowds of debtors in the massacres<br />

of Jews at London and York in 1189–1190. In 1275, Edward I of England passed the<br />

Statute of the Jewry which made usury illegal and linked it to blasphemy, in order to<br />

seize the assets of the violators. Scores of English Jews were arrested, 300 were<br />

hanged and their property went to the Crown. In 1290, all Jews were to be expelled<br />

from England, allowed to take only what they could carry; the rest of their property<br />

became the Crown's. Usury was cited as the official reason for the Edict of Expulsion;<br />

however, not all Jews were expelled: it was easy to avoid expulsion by converting to<br />

Christianity. Many other crowned heads of Europe expelled the Jews, although again<br />

Page 136 of 181


converts to Christianity were no longer considered Jewish (see the articles on marranos<br />

or crypto-Judaism).<br />

The growth of the Lombard bankers and pawnbrokers, who moved from city to city, was<br />

along the pilgrim routes.<br />

Die Wucherfrage is the title of a Lutheran Church–Missouri Synod<br />

work against usury from 1869. Usury is condemned in 19thcentury<br />

Missouri Synod doctrinal statements.<br />

In the 16th century, short-term interest rates dropped dramatically (from around 20–30%<br />

p.a. to around 9–10% p.a.). This was caused by refined commercial techniques,<br />

increased capital availability, the Reformation, and other reasons. The lower rates<br />

weakened religious scruples about lending at interest, although the debate did not<br />

cease altogether.<br />

The papal prohibition on usury meant that it was a sin to charge interest on a money<br />

loan. As set forth by Thomas Aquinas, the natural essence of money was as a measure<br />

of value or intermediary in exchange. The increase of money through usury violated this<br />

essence and according to the same Thomistic analysis, a just transaction was one<br />

characterized by an equality of exchange, one where each side received exactly his<br />

due. Interest on a loan, in excess of the principal, would violate the balance of an<br />

exchange between debtor and creditor and was therefore unjust.<br />

Charles Eisenstein has argued that pivotal change in the English-speaking world came<br />

with lawful rights to charge interest on lent money, particularly the 1545 Act, "An Act<br />

Against Usurie" (37 H. viii 9) of King Henry VIII of England.<br />

Judaism<br />

Religious Context<br />

Jews are forbidden from usury in dealing with fellow Jews, and this lending is to be<br />

considered tzedakah, or charity. However, there are permissions to charge interest on<br />

loans to non-Jews. This is outlined in the Jewish scriptures of the Torah, which<br />

Christians hold as part of the Old Testament, and other books of the Tanakh. From the<br />

Jewish Publication Society's 1917 Tanakh, with Christian verse numbers, where<br />

different, in parentheses:<br />

Exodus 22:24 (25)—If thou lend money to any of My people, even to the poor with thee,<br />

thou shalt not be to him as a creditor; neither shall ye lay upon him interest.<br />

Leviticus 25:36— Take thou no interest of him or increase; but fear thy God; that thy<br />

brother may live with thee.<br />

Leviticus 25:37— Thou shalt not give him thy money upon interest, nor give him thy<br />

victuals for increase.<br />

Page 137 of 181


Deuteronomy 23:20 (19)—Thou shalt not lend upon interest to thy brother: interest of<br />

money, interest of victuals, interest of anything that is lent upon interest.<br />

Deuteronomy 23:21 (20)—Unto a foreigner thou mayest lend upon interest; but unto thy<br />

brother thou shalt not lend upon interest; that the LORD thy God may bless thee in all<br />

that thou puttest thy hand unto, in the land whither thou goest in to possess it.<br />

Ezekiel 18:17—that hath withdrawn his hand from the poor, that hath not received<br />

interest nor increase, hath executed Mine ordinances, hath walked in My statutes; he<br />

shall not die for the iniquity of his father, he shall surely live.<br />

Psalm 15:5—He that putteth not out his money on interest, nor taketh a bribe against<br />

the innocent. He that doeth these things shall never be moved.<br />

Several historical rulings in Jewish law have mitigated the allowances for usury toward<br />

non-Jews. For instance, the 15th-century commentator Rabbi Isaac Abrabanel specified<br />

that the rubric for allowing interest does not apply to Christians or Muslims, because<br />

their faith systems have a common ethical basis originating from Judaism. The medieval<br />

commentator Rabbi David Kimchi extended this principle to non-Jews who show<br />

consideration for Jews, saying they should be treated with the same consideration when<br />

they borrow.<br />

Islam<br />

The following quotations are English translations from the Qur'an:<br />

Those who charge usury are in the same position as those controlled by the devil's<br />

influence. This is because they claim that usury is the same as commerce. However, God<br />

permits commerce, and prohibits usury. Thus, whoever heeds this commandment from<br />

his Lord, and refrains from usury, he may keep his past earnings, and his judgment rests<br />

with God. As for those who persist in usury, they incur Hell, wherein they abide forever<br />

(Al-Baqarah 2:275)<br />

God condemns usury, and blesses charities. God dislikes every sinning disbeliever.<br />

Those who believe and do good works and establish worship and pay the poor-due,<br />

their reward is with their Lord and there shall no fear come upon them neither shall they<br />

grieve. O you who believe, you shall observe God and refrain from all kinds of usury, if<br />

you are believers. If you do not, then expect a war from God and His messenger. But if<br />

you repent, you may keep your capitals, without inflicting injustice, or incurring injustice.<br />

If the debtor is unable to pay, wait for a better time. If you give up the loan as a charity,<br />

it would be better for you, if you only knew. (Al-Baqarah 2:276-280)<br />

O you who believe, you shall not take usury, compounded over and over. Observe God,<br />

that you may succeed. (Al-'Imran 3:130)<br />

Page 138 of 181


And for practicing usury, which was forbidden, and for consuming the people's money<br />

illicitly. We have prepared for the disbelievers among them painful retribution. (Al-Nisa<br />

4:161)<br />

The usury that is practiced to increase some people's wealth, does not gain anything at<br />

God. But if people give to charity, seeking God's pleasure, these are the ones who<br />

receive their reward many fold. (Ar-Rum 30:39)<br />

The attitude of Muhammad to usury is articulated in his Last Sermon<br />

O People, just as you regard this month, this day, this city as Sacred, so regard the life<br />

and property of every Muslim as a sacred trust. Return the goods entrusted to you to<br />

their rightful owners. Hurt no one so that no one may hurt you. Remember that you will<br />

indeed meet your LORD, and that HE will indeed reckon your deeds. ALLAH has<br />

forbidden you to take usury (interest), therefore all interest obligation shall henceforth be<br />

waived. Your capital, however, is yours to keep. You will neither inflict nor suffer any<br />

inequity. Allah has Judged that there shall be no interest and that all the interest due to<br />

Abbas ibn 'Abd'al Muttalib (Prophet's uncle) shall henceforth be waived...<br />

Christianity<br />

The first of the scholastic Christian theologians, Saint Anselm of Canterbury, led the<br />

shift in thought that labeled charging interest the same as theft. Previously usury had<br />

been seen as a lack of charity.<br />

St. Thomas Aquinas, the leading scholastic theologian of the Roman Catholic Church,<br />

argued charging of interest is wrong because it amounts to "double charging", charging<br />

for both the thing and the use of the thing. Aquinas said this would be morally wrong in<br />

Page 139 of 181


the same way as if one sold a bottle of wine, charged for the bottle of wine, and then<br />

charged for the person using the wine to actually drink it. Similarly, one cannot charge<br />

for a piece of cake and for the eating of the piece of cake. Yet this, said Aquinas, is<br />

what usury does. Money is a medium of exchange, and is used up when it is spent. To<br />

charge for the money and for its use (by spending) is therefore to charge for the money<br />

twice. It is also to sell time since the usurer charges, in effect, for the time that the<br />

money is in the hands of the borrower. Time, however, is not a commodity that anyone<br />

can charge. In condemning usury Aquinas was much influenced by the recently<br />

rediscovered philosophical writings of Aristotle and his desire to assimilate Greek<br />

philosophy with Christian theology. Aquinas argued that in the case of usury, as in other<br />

aspects of Christian revelation, Christian doctrine is reinforced by Aristotelian natural<br />

law rationalism. Aristotle's argument is that interest is unnatural, since money, as a<br />

sterile element, cannot naturally reproduce itself. Thus, usury conflicts with natural law<br />

just as it offends Christian revelation: see Thought of Thomas Aquinas.<br />

Outlawing usury did not prevent investment, but stipulated that in order for the investor<br />

to share in the profit he must share the risk. In short he must be a joint-venturer. Simply<br />

to invest the money and expect it to be returned regardless of the success of the<br />

venture was to make money simply by having money and not by taking any risk or by<br />

doing any work or by any effort or sacrifice at all, which is usury. St Thomas quotes<br />

Aristotle as saying that "to live by usury is exceedingly unnatural". Islam likewise<br />

condemns usury but allowed commerce (Al-Baqarah 2:275) - an alternative that<br />

suggests investment and sharing of profit and loss instead of sharing only profit through<br />

interests. Judaism condemns usury towards Jews, but allows it towards non-Jews.<br />

(Deut 23:19-20) St Thomas allows, however, charges for actual services provided. Thus<br />

a banker or credit-lender could charge for such actual work or effort as he did carry out<br />

e.g. any fair administrative charges. The Catholic Church, in a decree of the Fifth<br />

Council of the Lateran, expressly allowed such charges in respect of credit-unions run<br />

for the benefit of the poor known as "montes pietatis".<br />

In the 13th century Cardinal Hostiensis enumerated thirteen situations in which charging<br />

interest was not immoral. The most important of these was lucrum cessans (profits<br />

given up) which allowed for the lender to charge interest "to compensate him for profit<br />

foregone in investing the money himself." (Rothbard 1995, p. 46) This idea is very<br />

similar to opportunity cost. Many scholastic thinkers who argued for a ban on interest<br />

charges also argued for the legitimacy of lucrum cessans profits (e.g. Pierre Jean Olivi<br />

and St. Bernardino of Siena). However, Hostiensis' exceptions, including for lucrum<br />

cessans, were never accepted as official by the Roman Catholic Church.<br />

The Roman Catholic Church has always condemned usury, but in modern times, with<br />

the rise of capitalism and the disestablishment of the Catholic Church in majority<br />

Catholic countries, this prohibition on usury has not been enforced.<br />

Pope Benedict XIV's encyclical Vix Pervenit gives the reasons why usury is sinful:<br />

The nature of the sin called usury has its proper place and origin in a loan contract…<br />

[which] demands, by its very nature, that one return to another only as much as he has<br />

Page 140 of 181


eceived. The sin rests on the fact that sometimes the creditor desires more than he has<br />

given…, but any gain which exceeds the amount he gave is illicit and usurious.<br />

One cannot condone the sin of usury by arguing that the gain is not great or excessive,<br />

but rather moderate or small; neither can it be condoned by arguing that the borrower is<br />

rich; nor even by arguing that the money borrowed is not left idle, but is spent usefully…<br />

Usury in Literature<br />

Other Contexts<br />

In The Divine Comedy Dante places the usurers in the inner ring of the seventh circle of<br />

hell.<br />

Interest on loans, and the contrasting views on the morality of that practice held by Jews<br />

and Christians, is central to the plot of Shakespeare's play "The Merchant of Venice".<br />

Antonio is the merchant of the title, a Christian, who is forced by circumstance to borrow<br />

money from Shylock, a Jew.<br />

Shylock customarily charges interest on loans, seeing it as good business, while<br />

Antonio does not, viewing it as morally wrong. When Antonio defaults on his loan,<br />

Shylock famously demands the agreed upon penalty-a measured quantity of muscle<br />

from Antonio's chest.<br />

Page 141 of 181


This is the source of the phrase "a pound of flesh" often used to describe the dear price<br />

of a loan or business transaction. Shakespeare's play is a vivid portrait of the competing<br />

views of loans and use of interest, as well as the cultural strife between Jews and<br />

Christians that overlaps it.<br />

By the 18th century, usury was more often treated as a metaphor than a crime in itself,<br />

so Jeremy Bentham's Defense of Usury was not as shocking as it would have appeared<br />

two centuries earlier.<br />

In Honoré de Balzac's 1830 novel Gobseck, the title character, who is a usurer, is<br />

described as both "petty and great—a miser and a philosopher..." [39] The character<br />

Daniel Quilp in The Old Curiosity Shop by Charles Dickens is a usurer.<br />

In the early 20th century Ezra Pound's anti-usury poetry was not primarily based on the<br />

moral injustice of interest payments but on the fact that excess capital was no longer<br />

devoted to artistic patronage, as it could now be used for capitalist business investment.<br />

Usury and The law<br />

Usury law<br />

Magna Carta commands, "If any one has taken anything, whether much or little, by way<br />

of loan from Jews, and if he dies before that debt is paid, the debt shall not carry usury<br />

so long as the heir is under age, from whomsoever he may hold. And if that debt falls<br />

into our hands, we will take only the principal contained in the note."<br />

"When money is lent on a contract to receive not only the principal sum again, but also<br />

an increase by way of compensation for the use, the increase is called interest by those<br />

who think it lawful, and usury by those who do not." (William Blackstone's<br />

Commentaries on the Laws of England).<br />

United States<br />

Usury laws are state laws that specify the maximum legal interest rate at which loans<br />

can be made. In the United States, the primary legal power to regulate usury rests<br />

primarily with the states. Each U.S. state has its own statute that dictates how much<br />

interest can be charged before it is considered usurious or unlawful.<br />

If a lender charges above the lawful interest rate, a court will not allow the lender to sue<br />

to recover the unlawfully high interest, and some states will apply all payments made on<br />

the debt to the principal balance. In some states, such as New York), usurious loans are<br />

voided ab initio.<br />

The making of usurious loans is often called loan sharking. That term is sometimes also<br />

applied to the practice of making consumer loans without a license in jurisdictions that<br />

requires lenders to be licensed.<br />

Page 142 of 181


Federal Regulation<br />

On a federal level, Congress has never attempted to federally regulate interest rates on<br />

purely private transactions, but on the basis of past U.S. Supreme Court decisions,<br />

arguably the U.S. Congress might have the power to do so under the interstate<br />

commerce clause of Article I of the Constitution.<br />

Congress imposed a federal criminal penalty for unlawful interest rates through the<br />

Racketeer Influenced and Corrupt Organizations Act (RICO Statute), and its definition of<br />

"unlawful debt", which makes it a potential federal felony to lend money at an interest<br />

rate more than twice the local state usury rate and then try to collect that debt.<br />

It is a federal offense to use violence or threats to collect usurious interest (or any other<br />

sort).<br />

Separate federal rules apply to most banks. The U.S. Supreme Court held unanimously<br />

in the 1978 case, Marquette Nat. Bank of Minneapolis v. First of Omaha Service Corp.,<br />

that the National Banking Act of 1863 allowed nationally chartered banks to charge the<br />

legal rate of interest in their state regardless of the borrower's state of residence.<br />

In 1980, Congress passed the Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary<br />

Control Act. Among the Act's provisions, it exempted federally chartered savings banks,<br />

installment plan sellers and chartered loan companies from state usury limits. Combined<br />

with the Marquette decision that applied to National Banks, this effectively overrode all<br />

state and local usury laws. The 1968 Truth in <strong>Lending</strong> Act does not regulate rates,<br />

Page 143 of 181


except for some mortgages, but requires uniform or standardized disclosure of costs<br />

and charges.<br />

In the 1996 Smiley v. Citibank case, the Supreme Court further limited states' power to<br />

regulate credit card fees and extended the reach of the Marquette decision. The court<br />

held that the word "interest" used in the 1863 banking law included fees and, therefore,<br />

states could not regulate fees.<br />

Some members of Congress have tried to create a federal usury statute that would limit<br />

the maximum allowable interest rate, but the measures have not progressed. In July<br />

2010, the Dodd–Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, was signed<br />

into law by President Obama. The act provides for a Consumer Financial Protection<br />

Bureau to regulate some credit practices but has no interest rate limit.<br />

Texas<br />

State law in Texas also includes a provision for contracting for, charging, or receiving<br />

charges exceeding twice the amount authorized (A/K/A "double usury"). A person who<br />

violates this provision is liable to the obligor as an additional penalty for all principal or<br />

principal balance, as well as interest or time price differential. A person who is liable is<br />

also liable for reasonable attorney's fees incurred by the obligor.<br />

Canada<br />

Canada's Criminal Code limits the interest rate to 60% per year. The law is broadly<br />

written and Canada's courts have often intervened to remove ambiguity.<br />

Japan<br />

Japan has various laws restricting interest rates. Under civil law, the maximum interest<br />

rate is between 15% and 20% per year depending upon the principal amount (larger<br />

amounts having a lower maximum rate). Interest in excess of 20% is subject to criminal<br />

penalties (the criminal law maximum was 29.2% until it was lowered by legislation in<br />

2010). Default interest on late payments may be charged at up to 1.46 times the<br />

ordinary maximum (i.e., 21.9% to 29.2%), while pawn shops may charge interest of up<br />

to 9% per month (i.e., 108% per year, however, if the loan extends more than the<br />

normal short-term pawn shop loan, the 9% per month rate compounded can make the<br />

annual rate in excess of 180%, before then most of these transaction would result in<br />

any goods pawned being forfeited).<br />

Islamic Banking<br />

Avoidance Mechanisms and Interest-Free <strong>Lending</strong><br />

In a partnership or joint venture where money is lent, the creditor only provides the<br />

capital yet is guaranteed a fixed amount of profit. The debtor, however, puts in time and<br />

Page 144 of 181


effort, but is made to bear the risk of loss. Muslim scholars argue that such practice is<br />

unjust. As an alternative to usury, Islam strongly encourages charity and direct<br />

investment in which the creditor shares whatever profit or loss the business may incur<br />

(in modern terms, this amounts to an equity stake in the business).<br />

Non-Recourse Mortgages<br />

A non-recourse loan is secured by the value of property (usually real estate) owned by<br />

the debtor. However, unlike other loans, which oblige the debtor to repay the amount<br />

borrowed, a non-recourse loan is fully satisfied merely by the transfer of the property to<br />

the creditor, even if the property has declined in value and is worth less than the amount<br />

borrowed. When such a loan is created, the creditor bears the risk that the property will<br />

decline sharply in value (in which case the creditor is repaid with property worth less<br />

than the amount borrowed), and the debtor does not bear the risk of decrease in<br />

property value (because the debtor is guaranteed the right to use the property,<br />

regardless of value, to satisfy the debt.)<br />

Interest-Free Banks<br />

The JAK members bank is a usury-free saving and loaning system.<br />

Interest-Free Micro-<strong>Lending</strong><br />

Growth of the Internet internationally has enabled both business micro-lending through<br />

sites such as Kickstarter as well as through global micro-lending charities where lenders<br />

make small sums of money available on zero-interest terms. Persons lending money to<br />

Page 145 of 181


on-line micro-lending charity Kiva for example do not get paid any interest, although the<br />

end users to whom the loans are made may be charged interest by Kiva's partners in<br />

the country where the loan is used.<br />

Page 146 of 181


IX. References<br />

1. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/<strong>Predatory</strong>_lending<br />

2. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Subprime_lending<br />

3. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Poverty_industry<br />

4. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Economic_inequality<br />

5. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Redlining<br />

6. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Aporophobia<br />

7. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Economic_discrimination<br />

8. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Payday_loan<br />

9. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Refund_anticipation_loan<br />

10. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Title_loan<br />

11. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Loan_shark<br />

12. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Usury<br />

13. http://www.neoc.ne.gov/education/pdf/<strong>Predatory</strong><strong>Lending</strong>.pdf<br />

14. https://www.nber.org/papers/w19550.pdf<br />

15. http://www.ruralhome.org/storage/documents/predatoryandsubprime.pdf<br />

Page 147 of 181


Notes<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

Page 148 of 181


Notes<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

_____________________________________________________________________________________<br />

Page 149 of 181


Page 150 of 181


Attachment A<br />

What Is <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong>?<br />

Page 151 of 181


What is <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong>?<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong><br />

The Truth In <strong>Lending</strong> Act defines predatory lending as extending credit to a consumer based on<br />

the consumer’s collateral if, considering the consumers current and expected income, the<br />

consumer will be unable to make the scheduled payments to repay their obligation. In other<br />

words, predatory lending is lending to a homeowner in order to generate a claim on the<br />

equity of his or her house. There are various definitions for predatory lending, but in very<br />

general terms predatory lending is a process, often starting with misleading sales tactics, that<br />

culminates in the origination of a loan to a borrower who is paying too much in fees, interest or<br />

insurance. This person may not fully understand or may not be aware of all the provisions of the<br />

contact; and generally they do not have the financial capacity to repay the loan.<br />

All Sub Prime Lenders are Not <strong>Predatory</strong> Lenders<br />

While sub prime lenders charge higher interest rates and fees than conventional lenders, these<br />

fees usually correspond to a higher degree of risk to the borrower. However, there are some sub<br />

prime lenders who engage in unethical predatory lending practices based on excessive rates and<br />

fees. These lenders distort the commonly used sales and underwriting tools to the detriment of<br />

the borrowers.<br />

Who Is the Target of <strong>Predatory</strong> Lenders?<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> lenders look for homeowners who have substantial equity in their homes, but need<br />

cash or have poor credit. <strong>Predatory</strong> lenders thrive on a consumers need for immediate cash or<br />

lack of familiarity with the standard credit products and practices. To be considered an ideal<br />

target of a predatory lender, the individual will have minimal cash flow and savings, a large<br />

amount of equity in their homes and limited experience with financial services, or even may be<br />

on a fixed income. Geographically speaking, these people prey on residents of lower income<br />

communities, minorities, women and elder individuals who are disproportionately victims of<br />

predatory lenders.<br />

Tactics that <strong>Predatory</strong> Lenders Use<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> lenders use a variety of tactics to generate a claim of a homeowner’s equity. Some of<br />

these tactics are high interest rates and high points. Also, there are balloon payments and<br />

negative amortization; packing or padding costs and fees; flipping; high LTV loans, and locking<br />

borrowers in.


How We Can Protect Ourselves from <strong>Predatory</strong> Lenders<br />

There are a few simple steps that homeowners can take to protect themselves.<br />

1. Follow the basic rule of buyer beware; never sign a contact or any piece of paper without<br />

reading it;<br />

2. Carefully and fully understand what it obligates you to do; if possible, get an attorney or<br />

trusted financial advisor to review it before you sign it.<br />

3. Don’t agree to a loan if you don’t think you can make the payments;<br />

4. For any loan, make sure you understand all of the terms before you sign it;<br />

5. If the annual percentage rate of the loan is a lot higher than the interest rate quoted on the<br />

loan, there may be unnecessary fees attached; compare the APR and interest rate on your<br />

loan with the APR and interest rate offered by conventional bankers;<br />

6. Shop around, don’t let anyone rush you into a decision on a loan or home improvement<br />

contract; go first to a conventional bank if you need a loan;<br />

7. Don’t agree to a loan without knowing the amount of closing cost, fees and other upfront<br />

costs;<br />

These are simply a few of the things you can do; there are a lot more. Education is the key to<br />

avoid becoming the victim of a predatory lender.


Page 152 of 181


Attachment B<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong><br />

and The Subprime Crisis<br />

Page 153 of 181


NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES<br />

PREDATORY LENDING AND THE SUBPRIME CRISIS<br />

Sumit Agarwal<br />

Gene Amromin<br />

Itzhak Ben-David<br />

Souphala Chomsisengphet<br />

Douglas D. Evanoff<br />

Working Paper 19550<br />

http://www.nber.org/papers/w19550<br />

NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH<br />

1050 Massachusetts Avenue<br />

Cambridge, MA 02138<br />

October 2013<br />

We thank Caitlin Kearns for outstanding research assistance. We thank Amit Seru and an anonymous<br />

referee for important and insightful comments. Thanks are also due to participants at numerous conferences<br />

and seminars for their helpful feedback. Ben-David’s research is supported by the Dice Center and<br />

the Neil Klatskin Chair in Finance and Real Estate. The views in this paper are those of the authors<br />

and may not reflect those of the Federal Reserve System, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, the<br />

Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, or the National Bureau of Economic Research.<br />

NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peerreviewed<br />

or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official<br />

NBER publications.<br />

© 2013 by Sumit Agarwal, Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet, and Douglas<br />

D. Evanoff. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted<br />

without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.


<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> and the Subprime Crisis<br />

Sumit Agarwal, Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet, and Douglas<br />

D. Evanoff<br />

NBER Working Paper No. 19550<br />

October 2013<br />

JEL No. D14,D18<br />

ABSTRACT<br />

We measure the effect of an anti-predatory pilot program (Chicago, 2006) on mortgage default rates<br />

to test whether predatory lending was a key element in fueling the subprime crisis. Under the program,<br />

risky borrowers and/or risky mortgage contracts triggered review sessions by housing counselors who<br />

shared their findings with the state regulator. The pilot cut market activity in half, largely through<br />

the exit of lenders specializing in risky loans and through decline in the share of subprime borrowers.<br />

Our results suggest that predatory lending practices contributed to high mortgage default rates among<br />

subprime borrowers, raising them by about a third.<br />

Sumit Agarwal<br />

Associate Professor of Finance and Real Estate<br />

NUS Business School<br />

Mochtar Raidy Building, BIZ1<br />

15 Kent Ridge Road<br />

Singapore, 119245<br />

ushakri@yahoo.com<br />

Gene Amromin<br />

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago<br />

230 South LaSalle Street<br />

Chicago, IL 60604-1413<br />

gamromin@frbchi.org<br />

Souphala Chomsisengphet<br />

Office of the Comptroller of the Currency<br />

Department of Treasury<br />

Washington, DC.<br />

souphala.chomsisengphet@occ.treas.gov<br />

Douglas D. Evanoff<br />

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago<br />

230 South LaSalle Street<br />

Chicago, IL 60604-1413<br />

devanoff@frbchi.org<br />

Itzhak Ben-David<br />

Fisher College of Business<br />

The Ohio State University<br />

2100 Neil Avenue<br />

Columbus, OH 43210<br />

and NBER<br />

bendavid@fisher.osu.edu


1. Introduction<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> lending has been the focus of intense academic and policy debate surrounding<br />

the recent housing crisis. <strong>Predatory</strong> lending—commonly defined as imposing unfair and abusive<br />

loan terms on borrowers, often through aggressive sales tactics, or loans that contain terms and<br />

conditions that ultimately harm borrowers (GAO, 2004; FDIC, 2006)—has also captured much<br />

media attention and appears to be a major concern for borrowers. 1 While all agree that mortgages<br />

with abusive terms are costly to borrowers and to taxpayers, the extent of the phenomenon is<br />

hard to quantify and is politically charged (e.g., Agarwal and Evanoff, 2013; Engel and McCoy,<br />

2007). Several journalistic accounts and industry reports take the position that predatory lending<br />

had a central role in creating and feeding the housing bubble, particularly through subprime loan<br />

originations (e.g., the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, 2010; Hudson, 2010; Center for<br />

Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>, 2009). To our knowledge, there is no systematic evidence to date<br />

measuring the effect of predatory lending on mortgage performance. Our paper attempts to fill<br />

this gap.<br />

In academic literature, predatory lending is modeled as cases in which lenders possess<br />

private information about borrowers’ future ability to repay loans and encourage mortgages with<br />

terms that borrowers cannot afford (Bond, Musto, and Yilmaz, 2009). This model clearly<br />

portrays the empirical challenge in measuring predatory lending: because it is difficult to observe<br />

lenders’ informational advantage over borrowers, it is hard to measure the size of the<br />

phenomenon and assess its role in precipitating the subprime mortgage crisis.<br />

In this paper, we attempt to overcome this challenge by analyzing the effects of a pilot<br />

anti-predatory legislative program implemented in Chicago near the peak of the real-estate<br />

boom. The pilot required “low-credit-quality” applicants and applicants for “risky” mortgages to<br />

submit their loan offers from state-licensed lenders for third-party review by HUD-certified<br />

financial counselors. As described in greater detail below, the fact that the pilot applied only in<br />

certain areas during a specific time period, only to certain borrower and mortgage contract<br />

1 Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales (2013) find that about half of surveyed borrowers would be willing to strategically<br />

default on their mortgage should they discover that their lender was involved in predatory lending.<br />

2


combinations, and only to a specific set of lenders allows us to parse out its effect on the<br />

availability of mortgage credit with predatory characteristics and to evaluate ex post mortgage<br />

performance. The study draws on detailed loan-level data from public and proprietary sources, as<br />

well as data provided by one of the largest counseling agencies involved in the pilot.<br />

Our empirical strategy is based on classic difference-in-differences analysis that contrasts<br />

changes in mortgage market composition and loan performance in the treated sample with those<br />

in a control sample. Unlike bacteria in a petri dish, lenders and borrowers could respond to the<br />

mandated treatment either by leaving the pilot area or by adapting to the new rules. Hence, we<br />

pay particular attention to endogenous selection of lenders and borrowers out of treatment. If<br />

predatory lending resulted in significantly higher default rates and thus precipitated the crisis, we<br />

should observe a significant reduction in default rates in the targeted market as predatory lending<br />

declined.<br />

We find that following passage of the legislative pilot, the number of active lenders<br />

declined disproportionately in the target geographic area. The decline was particularly<br />

pronounced among state-licensed lenders that specialized in the origination of subprime loans,<br />

many of which included contract features deemed objectionable by the legislation. Nearly half of<br />

the state-licensed lenders exited the pilot zip codes, more than double the exit rate in the control<br />

areas. The remaining lenders made fewer risky loans and originated credit to borrowers with<br />

higher credit quality. Specifically, we show that the volumes of loan applications and<br />

originations by state-licensed lenders in the pilot area declined by 51% and 61%, respectively.<br />

The average FICO score of borrowers who were able to obtain credit during the pilot period was<br />

8 points higher (15% of one standard deviation).<br />

The resulting mortgages issued in the pilot area were less likely to feature “risky”<br />

characteristics (as defined by legislators) that would subject them to counselor review. For<br />

instance, there were fewer loans with negative amortization or prepayment penalties, as well as<br />

fewer low-documentation and low down-payment loans. This set of findings suggests, therefore,<br />

3


that the legislation had a deep impact on market activity and likely drove much of the predatory<br />

lending activity from the market.<br />

Yet, although the pilot dramatically affected market activity, it had a relatively moderate<br />

effect on borrower default rates. When we restrict our analysis to the subset of market<br />

participants directly targeted by the pilot—subprime borrowers and state-licensed lenders—we<br />

find improvements in 18-month default rates of 6 to 7 percentage points, relative to the<br />

unconditional default rate of 27%. Moreover, all of the statistically measurable improvement in<br />

loan performance came from changes in the composition of lenders, many of whom were driven<br />

out by the legislation. These estimates suggest that while predatory lending contributed to high<br />

default rates, it may have not been as instrumental in precipitating the financial crisis as<br />

popularly believed.<br />

In practice, it may be difficult to distinguish predatory lending practices from merely<br />

“aggressive” ones. To make headway in separating the two, we exploit another feature of the<br />

anti-predatory program. The heart of the HB4050 pilot was the imposition of a mortgage review<br />

requirement for risky borrowers and for those who chose risky loans. During the review,<br />

counselors identified loans that were suspected of having predatory characteristics, e.g., loans<br />

with above-market rates, loans appearing to be unaffordable based on borrower characteristics,<br />

and loans with indications of fraud. We analyze a sample of 121 loans for which we have<br />

detailed counselor assessment data. 2 We conjecture that loans that were flagged as predatory and<br />

yet were pursued by borrowers (i.e., borrowers ignored the counselors’ advice) were more likely<br />

to default relative to non-flagged loans. Indeed, we find that these predatory loans had 18-month<br />

delinquency rates that were 6.5 percentage points higher than nonflagged loans. The difference<br />

in delinquency rates was even higher for loans with fraud indicia, which had a 12.3 percentage<br />

point differential.<br />

2 For an in-depth analysis of the role of mortgage counseling, see Agarwal, Amromin, Ben-David, Chomsisengphet,<br />

and Evanoff (2010, 2012).<br />

4


Our findings have important implications for policymakers. First, the pilot program was a<br />

blunt policy tool that swept up a wide swath of borrowers, lenders, and products and caused<br />

substantial market disruption. Second, despite the measureable improvements in mortgage<br />

performance in the subpopulation most affected by the pilot, default rates remained alarmingly<br />

high, suggesting that predatory lending practices may have played a relatively limited role in<br />

triggering the crisis. In fact, because some of the loans eliminated by the pilot may have been<br />

aggressive rather than predatory, we are likely to be overstating the effect of predatory lending<br />

practices. Third, evaluation of welfare gains or losses stemming from such policy programs is<br />

fraught with difficulties, many of which are exacerbated by the distortions that exist in housing<br />

markets. Our paper does not attempt to gauge the welfare consequences of the pilot, and<br />

policymakers should be aware that such consequences are difficult to measure. Finally, the<br />

HB4050 pilot demonstrates the political difficulty of implementing policies that “lean” against<br />

asset bubbles. 3<br />

Specifically, interest groups (real-estate professionals as well as community<br />

activists) protested against the legislation. Both groups viewed the preceding run-up in realestate<br />

prices as an opportunity for their constituents to achieve their goals (profits or housing<br />

access), and they therefore perceived the legislation as harmful.<br />

Our paper relates to two strands of the literature. The first explores the role of<br />

intermediaries in precipitating the financial crisis. Keys et al. (2010) show that securitization<br />

leads to lax screening by mortgage lenders. Ben-David (2011, 2012) finds that intermediaries<br />

expanded the mortgage market by enabling otherwise ineligible borrowers to misrepresent asset<br />

valuations to obtain larger loans, and by pushing buyers to overpay for properties. Rajan, Seru,<br />

and Vig (2013) show that soft information about borrowers is lost as the chain of intermediaries<br />

in the origination process becomes longer, leading to a decline in the quality of originated<br />

mortgages. Finally, see Agarwal and Ben-David (2013) who study the role of loan officer<br />

compensation leading up to the financial crisis.<br />

3 As discussed in detail in Section 2.2, the program was terminated early, providing further evidence of the high cost<br />

of identifying predatory lending—the regulators could not withstand the political pressure associated with<br />

implementing the program.<br />

5


The second strand of the literature studies predatory lending in personal finance. In<br />

particular, researchers have focused on the debate about whether payday lending helps or<br />

exploits borrowers. Morse (2011) shows that borrowers in areas with payday lending are more<br />

resilient to natural disasters. In contrast, Melzer (2011) uses cross-border variation and finds no<br />

evidence that payday lending alleviates hardship. Bertrand and Morse (2011) find that providing<br />

additional information about loans to payday borrowers reduces loan take-up. Agarwal, Skiba,<br />

and Tobacman (2009) show that payday borrowers preserve access to formal credit through their<br />

credit cards while paying very high interest rates on their payday loans.<br />

2. Illinois <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> Database Pilot Program (HB4050)<br />

2.1. Description of the Pilot Program<br />

In 2005, the Illinois legislature passed a bill intended to curtail predatory lending.<br />

Although the state had a number of anti-predatory provisions in place, like prevailing practices<br />

elsewhere in the country, they were based on loan characteristics. Some political leaders in<br />

Illinois became concerned about the ease with which lenders could avoid the trigger criteria of<br />

anti-predatory programs by creatively packaging their loans. For instance, balloon mortgages<br />

targeted by regulations were replaced with adjustable rate mortgages (ARMs) with short fixedrate<br />

periods and steep rate reset slopes (the so-called 2/28 and 3/27 hybrid ARMs). 4<br />

Consequently, the new bill included a new enforcement mechanism and tougher penalties for<br />

noncompliance. It also sought to educate borrowers prior to closing on their new mortgage loans.<br />

To that effect, the legislation sponsored by Illinois House Speaker Michael Madigan<br />

mandated review of mortgage offers for “high-risk borrowers” by HUD-certified housing<br />

counselors. High-risk borrowers were defined as applicants with sufficiently low credit scores or<br />

sufficiently risky product choices. The legislation set the FICO score threshold for mandatory<br />

counseling at 620, with an additional provision that borrowers with FICO scores in the 621–650<br />

4 For a detailed analysis of the impact of the state anti-predatory lending laws on the type of mortgage products used<br />

in the market, see Bostic et al. (2012).<br />

6


ange receive counseling if they chose what the regulation defined as high-risk mortgage<br />

products. Such mortgages included interest-only loans, loans with interest rate adjustments<br />

within three years, loans underwritten on the basis of stated income (low-documentation loans),<br />

and repeated refinancings within the past 12 months (Category I loans). Borrowers were subject<br />

to counseling regardless of their FICO score if they took out loans that allowed negative<br />

amortization, had prepayment penalties, or had closing costs in excess of 5% (Category II loans).<br />

The proposal was modeled on a Federal Housing Administration (FHA) program from the<br />

1970s, 5 and it generated a lot of excitement among Illinois lawmakers, who passed House Bill<br />

4050 (HB4050) on the last day of the 2005 legislative session. HB4050 applied only to loans<br />

offered by state-licensed mortgage lenders, as the state lacks legal authority to regulate federally<br />

chartered institutions and generally exempts them from mortgage licensing requirements.<br />

Furthermore, HB4050 applied only to select neighborhoods, namely, ten zip codes on the City of<br />

Chicago’s South Side.<br />

The need for a high-risk borrower counseling session was determined on the day of the<br />

application, and the borrower had ten days to contact the agency to schedule it. The lender was<br />

required to cover the $300 cost of the session. The goal of these sessions, lasting one to two<br />

hours, was to discuss the terms of the specific offer for a home purchase or refinancing loan and<br />

to explain their meaning and consequences to the prospective borrower. The counselors were not<br />

supposed to advise borrowers about their optimal mortgage choice in the sense of Campbell and<br />

Cocco (2003); rather, they were to warn them against common pitfalls. The counselors were also<br />

expected to verify the loan application information about the borrower (e.g., income and<br />

expenses). None of the recommendations was binding—borrowers could always choose to<br />

proceed with the loan offer at hand.<br />

At the end of the session, the counselor recorded a number of findings in a stateadministered<br />

database. These included whether the lender charged excessive fees, whether the<br />

5 See “Illinois Tries New Tack Against <strong>Predatory</strong> Loans” by Amy Merrick, Wall Street Journal Online, 21 August<br />

2007, http://online.wsj.com/article/SB118765937527803664.html.<br />

7


loan interest rate was in excess of the market rate, whether the borrower understood the<br />

transaction and/or could afford the loan, and so forth. Even though HB4050 established the<br />

database for pilot evaluation purposes, lenders feared that the state’s collection of this<br />

information could lead to potential regulatory (e.g., license revocation) or legal (e.g., class-action<br />

lawsuits) actions.<br />

As another direct penalty for noncompliance, lenders lost the right to foreclose on a<br />

delinquent property. Under HB4050, title companies did not receive a “safe harbor” provision<br />

for “good faith compliance with the law.” As a result, clerical errors at any point in the loan<br />

application process could potentially invalidate the title, making the lender unable to pursue<br />

foreclosure. 6,7 Finally, lenders reportedly feared losing some of their ability to steer borrowers<br />

toward high margin products.<br />

The new regulation imposed costs on borrowers as well. Even though session fees had to<br />

be borne by the lender, anecdotal evidence suggests brokers attempted to pass them on to<br />

borrowers in the form of higher closing costs and administrative charges (Bates and Van Zandt,<br />

2007, and personal communication with mortgage counselors). HB4050 also imposed time costs<br />

on borrowers. By lengthening the expected time until closing, the new law could force borrowers<br />

to pay for longer credit lock periods, further raising loan costs.<br />

Both the counseling session and the independent collection of borrower data allowed<br />

counselors to form their own assessment of the borrower’s creditworthiness. Effectively, the<br />

counselors were able to elicit private information that may or may not have been used by lenders<br />

6 According to the Cook County Recorder of Deeds, even federally regulated lenders had to procure a certificate of<br />

exemption from HB4050 to obtain a clean title. Consequently, all lenders were affected to at least some degree by<br />

the legislation.<br />

7 This feature of HB4050 caused some investors to warn about their willingness to purchase loans originated in pilot<br />

zip codes. Most of these warnings stipulated that to be eligible for purchase, a loan had to receive a certificate of<br />

counseling or of exemption from counseling. However, the presence of one of these certificates was a requirement<br />

for loan closing and recording, which itself is a prerequisite for sale or securitization under standard purchase<br />

criteria. It is thus unclear whether would-be investors had any additional reasons to worry about recorded loans<br />

under HB4050. In any event, the share of securitized loans in the treated zip codes declined from 83% to 70%<br />

during the pilot period. However, this decline was not appreciably different from that in the control zip codes. It thus<br />

appears that the pilot did not have a sizable impact on secondary market activity counter to the historical experience<br />

in Georgia and New Jersey discussed in Keys et al. (2010).<br />

8


to make approval and/or pricing decisions and then give that information to state regulators. This<br />

external verification process, together with strict penalties for noncompliance, likely provided<br />

strong incentives for lenders to better screen out marginal applications prior to referring<br />

approved applications to counseling. One extreme form of screening was to cease lending in<br />

HB4050 areas altogether.<br />

A report by the nonprofit Housing Action Illinois (2007) summarized the counselors’<br />

assessments of HB4050 covered loans. Over the course of the pilot, about 1,200 borrowers had<br />

their loan offers reviewed by 41 HUD-certified counselors from 11 agencies. Housing Action<br />

Illinois (2007) reports that 9% of the mortgages were deemed to have indications of fraud. About<br />

half of the borrowers were advised that they could not afford the loan or were close to not being<br />

able to do so. For 22% of the borrowers, loan rates were determined to be more than 300 basis<br />

points above the market rate. For 9% of the borrowers, the counselors found a discrepancy<br />

between the loan documentation and the verbal description of the mortgage. Perhaps most<br />

alarmingly, an overwhelming majority of borrowers who were receiving adjustable rate loans did<br />

not understand that their mortgage payment was not fixed over the life of the loan.<br />

2.2. Early Termination of the Pilot Program<br />

The program was meant to run as a four-year pilot in select Chicago neighborhoods.<br />

Afterwards, its coverage was expected to be expanded to the entire metropolitan area. In spite of<br />

vocal opposition from community-based groups and affected lenders, Illinois politicians<br />

clamored to have their districts included in the pilot. This effort by politicians looks particularly<br />

ironic in retrospect, given the eventual response of the population in the pilot area.<br />

As mentioned earlier, only loans offered by state-licensed mortgage lenders were subject<br />

to HB4050. In disadvantaged Chicago neighborhoods, much of the lending had been done<br />

through state-licensed mortgage bankers, which presented themselves as a local and nimble<br />

alternative to the more traditional bank lenders. 8 Consequently, the legislation was likely to<br />

8 Using the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) data described in detail in Section 3, we estimate that statelicensed<br />

mortgage bankers accounted for 64% of mortgage loans originations in the HB4050 zip codes during 2005.<br />

9


increase the regulatory burden on the very entities providing credit in the selected pilot area. The<br />

possibility that this could result in credit rationing prompted many observers to voice concern<br />

about the potential effect of HB4050 on housing values in the selected zip codes.<br />

The geographic focus of the legislation differed substantially from typical regulatory<br />

approaches that require counseling for certain loan types (Bates and Van Zandt, 2007). This<br />

feature of the legislation generated considerable opposition from community activists and<br />

residents and prompted several lawsuits. Because the selected pilot area was overwhelmingly<br />

populated by Hispanic and African American residents (81%, see Table 1, Panel A), the<br />

selection also prompted heated accusations of discriminatory intent on the part of lawmakers.<br />

Specifically, community activists formed an organization named the Coalition to Rescind<br />

HB4050, led by John Paul (president of the Greater Englewood Family Taskforce) and Julie<br />

Santos (an immigrants’ rights activist). In the media and through vocal protests at the grassroots<br />

level, the organization put legal and political pressure on politicians to revoke the legislation. 9<br />

The other group to oppose HB4050 comprised mortgage lenders and real-estate brokers,<br />

who claimed that the bill imposed onerous costs on real-estate professionals and that it reduced<br />

market activity. This group also applied considerable pressure to abolish HB4050, ranging from<br />

highly publicized refusals to lend in the pilot zip codes to joining legal actions against the<br />

legislation. 10<br />

As mortgage lenders threatened to withdraw from the pilot zip codes en masse, and as the<br />

tide of concerns about credit access began to rise, opposition to HB4050 reached fever pitch. 11<br />

The pilot program was suspended indefinitely on January 17, 2007 after only 20 weeks of<br />

9 The Chicago Tribune reported on November 2, 2006 that a group of residents and members of the real-estate<br />

community submitted a lawsuit against the state, claiming discrimination.<br />

10 The unusual confluence of interests between community activists and real-estate professionals in opposing the<br />

same regulatory action is reminiscent of Yandle’s (1983, 1999) “Bootleggers and Baptists” theory. The classic<br />

example of this theory is the banning of Sunday sales of alcohol—a regulation supported by both bootleggers and<br />

Baptists. The former endorsed the legislation because it allowed them to maintain the business of illegally selling<br />

liquor without competition. The latter approved of the regulation because it directly supported their objective of<br />

discouraging consumption of alcoholic beverages.<br />

11 The record of a public hearing held on November 27, 2006 provides a good illustration of the acrimony<br />

surrounding HB4050 (see http://www.idfpr.com/newsrls/032107HB4050PublicMeeting112706.pdf).<br />

10


operation. To provide some of the flavor of the public debate, we summarize the main news<br />

items about the HB4050 legislation in the national and local media in the Appendix.<br />

2.3. How Was the Pilot Program Area Selected?<br />

HB4050 instructed the state regulatory body (Department of Financial and Professional<br />

Regulation, or IDFPR) to designate a pilot area on the basis of “the high rate of foreclosure on<br />

residential home mortgages that is primarily the result of predatory lending practices.” The pilot<br />

area announced by IDFPR in February 2006 encompassed ten contiguous zip codes on the<br />

southwest side of Chicago (the solid shaded areas in Figure 1). 12 Four of these zip codes were<br />

located in Illinois House Speaker Madigan’s district.<br />

Table 1 summarizes some of the key demographic and mortgage characteristics for the<br />

pilot area and the rest of the City of Chicago. 13 The mortgage data come from the First American<br />

CoreLogic LoanPerformance data set on securitized, subprime and Alt-A mortgages (henceforth,<br />

the LP data). Panel A shows that IDFPR’s decision at the time was based on the fact that these<br />

zip codes had substantially higher default rates (Column (1)) compared to the rest of the city<br />

(Column (3)), even though they experienced stronger growth in house prices. 14,15 The pilot zip<br />

codes were also predominantly minority-populated and had much higher rates of unemployment<br />

and poverty (Panel A) relative to the rest of Chicago. A simple comparison of population counts<br />

and the total number of loan originations in the nonprime-LP data strongly suggests that the<br />

HB4050 area had a disproportional share of subprime and Alt-A mortgages.<br />

12 The HB4050 zip codes are: 60620, 60621, 60623, 60628, 60629, 60632, 60636, 60638, 60643, and 60652.<br />

13 Panel A also provides this information for the set of 12 zip codes that comprise one of our control samples—zip<br />

codes similar to those affected by HB4050 but not chosen for the pilot. Their selection is discussed in detail in<br />

Section 3. The comparisons here are made between the ten HB4050 zip codes and the 31 Chicago zip codes that<br />

exclude both the HB4050 and the 12 control zip codes.<br />

14 In this table, we use mortgage characteristics and performance for 2005 because this was the information set<br />

available to legislators at the beginning of 2006, when the legislation was voted on.<br />

15 Default is defined as a 90+ day delinquency, foreclosure, or real-estate owned within 18 months of origination.<br />

11


3. Data and Selection of Control Groups and Empirical Test Design<br />

3.1. Data Sources<br />

Our study relies on several complementary sources of data that cover the calendar years<br />

2005–2007. First, we use data collected under the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) to<br />

assess elements of supply and demand for credit. In the absence of loan application and<br />

counseling data collected under the statutory authority of HB4050, we turn to HMDA as the next<br />

best source of information on loan application volume, rejection rates, and so forth. Using<br />

information from HUD and hand-collected data, we distinguish between lenders who specialize<br />

in prime and subprime loans, as well as between lenders that are licensed by Illinois and those<br />

exempt from licensing. Because the effect of the legislation was likely to be felt most acutely by<br />

state-licensed subprime lenders, we use this list to refine our analysis. Furthermore, the HMDA<br />

data allow us to examine how HB4050 affected credit supply along the extensive margin, i.e., to<br />

identify lenders that left the market altogether. Overall, the HMDA data include 92,658 loans<br />

that were originated in the HB4050 zip codes during the 2005–2007 period.<br />

We also use the First American CoreLogic LoanPerformance (LP) database to assess the<br />

effect of HB4050 on contract type and performance of mortgages originated in the treated zip<br />

codes during 2005–2007. The LP data set includes detailed borrower and loan information such<br />

as FICO scores and debt service-to-income (DTI) and loan-to-value (LTV) ratios as well as<br />

mortgage terms, including maturity, product type (e.g., fixed or adjustable rate mortgage),<br />

interest rate, and interest rate spread. It also contains information on whether a given loan has a<br />

prepayment penalty, allows negative amortization, or required full documentation in<br />

underwriting. These and other characteristics of the LP data are summarized in Table 1, Panels B<br />

and C. FICO scores allow us to determine which borrowers in the HB4050 zip codes were<br />

automatically or conditionally subject to loan counseling. The LP data set includes 37,564<br />

mortgage loans originated in Chicago zip codes in 2005–2007.<br />

Because the LP data do not include information about the identity of the mortgage<br />

originator for loans, we need to match observations in the HMDA and LP data sets to examine<br />

12


the effects of the legislation. We match on the basis of the zip code, loan amount, and date of<br />

origination. Our matched data set yields 18,724 observations in the HB4050 zip codes.<br />

In the later part of our analysis, we use information from one of the counseling agencies.<br />

These data are part of the database constructed under the HB4050 legislation, which includes<br />

information on original mortgage offers reviewed during 191 counseling sessions. We match<br />

these data to the Cook County Recorder of Deeds and LP data sets to obtain loan characteristics<br />

on the counseled loans. The resulting data set includes 121 loans (other loans may not have been<br />

securitized and, therefore, not included in the LP data set). We use this data set to gauge the<br />

extent to which counseling had a direct effect on mortgage choice.<br />

Finally, we use Census and IRS data to control for zip code–level characteristics of<br />

income and population composition.<br />

3.2. Constructing a Zip Code–Based Control Group<br />

To evaluate the effect of the HB4050 legislation, we develop control samples that are<br />

similar to the pilot area but are unaffected by the legislation. As discussed in Section 2.3, the<br />

selection of treated zip codes was driven by their demographic and mortgage characteristics, as<br />

well as by political considerations. In fact, HB4050 zip codes exhibit characteristics that are far<br />

from unique in the Chicago area. We use this information to construct a control group that is<br />

meant to resemble the pilot area in terms of its pretreatment socioeconomic characteristics and<br />

housing market conditions. Without the intervention, we plausibly expect the HB4050 zip codes<br />

would have experienced the same changes in outcome variables as our control group zip codes.<br />

To develop the control group, we move beyond the univariate metric of foreclosure rates to a set<br />

of measures identifying economically disadvantaged inner-city neighborhoods.<br />

In particular, we use 2005 IRS zip code–level income statistics, as well as the 2000<br />

Census shares of minority population and of those living below the poverty level, and the<br />

unemployment rate to identify zip codes within the City of Chicago limits that have similar<br />

characteristics and the smallest geographic distance from the HB4050 zip codes. The resulting<br />

13


12–zip code area has about as many residents as the treatment area and experienced a similar<br />

path of house price changes, as summarized in Column (2), Panel A of Table 1. The statistics in<br />

Panel B of Table 1 corroborate our conclusion that the control zip codes are similar to the treated<br />

area in terms of their high default and delinquency rates, low borrower FICO scores, and<br />

disproportionate reliance on riskier mortgage products. 16 Judging by the spirit and the letter of<br />

stated legislative guidelines, these zip codes (shown by the striped area in Figure 1) could have<br />

plausibly been selected for HB4050 treatment. 17<br />

The HMDA database contains 80,876 loans originated in the 12–zip code control sample<br />

during the 2005–2007 period. The control sample contains 34,451 loan originations in the LP<br />

data set, 17,759 of which can be matched with HMDA data.<br />

3.3. Constructing a Synthetic Zip Code Control Sample<br />

To further establish the empirical robustness of our analysis, we construct a synthetic<br />

HB4050-like area in the spirit of Abadie and Gardeazabal (2003). 18 Instead of identifying a<br />

similar but untreated set of zip codes, we build up a comparison sample loan by loan, by<br />

matching on the basis of observable loan characteristics. Specifically, for each of the loans issued<br />

in the ten–zip code HB4050 area, we look for a loan most similar to it that was issued elsewhere<br />

within the City of Chicago in the same month. The metric for similarity is the geometric distance<br />

in terms of standardized values of the borrower’s FICO score, the loan’s DTI and LTV ratios, the<br />

log of home value, and the loan’s intended purpose (purchase or refinancing). Once a loan is<br />

matched to an HB4050-area loan, it is removed from the set of potential matches and the process<br />

16 In an earlier version of the paper, we used the reverse sequence to construct the control sample. That is, we built<br />

up the set of control zip codes by minimizing the distance in observed mortgage characteristics in the pre-HB4050<br />

LP data. Afterward we checked for similarities in socioeconomic characteristics between the treatment and control<br />

areas. All of the results reported below are robust to the definition of the control area and are available upon request.<br />

17 The control area comprises the following zip codes: 60609, 60617, 60619, 60624, 60633, 60637, 60639, 60644,<br />

60649, 60651, 60655, and 60827.<br />

18 It would be ideal to look at transactions that lie on either side of the border between the HB4050 and the control<br />

zip codes to tease out the effect of the counseling mandate. Unfortunately, the LP data do not contain street<br />

addresses.<br />

14


is repeated for the next HB4050-area loan. The resulting synthetic HB4050-like area is made up<br />

of observations from all 43 of the non-HB4050 Chicago zip codes. Not surprisingly, 65% of the<br />

observations in this synthetic area come from the 12 comparable zip codes identified in the<br />

preceding section on the basis of their socioeconomic characteristics.<br />

In Table 1, Panel B, we compare the characteristics of borrowers and mortgages in the<br />

treated zip codes sample to those in the synthetic control sample. The panel shows that for each<br />

loan characteristic the samples have very similar properties. Because we are not constrained by<br />

geographic proximity, the synthetic sample more closely matches the loans in the HB4050<br />

treatment area than does the control sample. However, all three samples display remarkably<br />

similar characteristics.<br />

3.4. Design of Tests: HB4050 Legislation as an Exogenous Shock to <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong><br />

To recap our data summary, the majority of lending in the HB4050 area was done by<br />

state-licensed lenders specializing in subprime loans. Many of these loans had short reset periods<br />

(hybrid ARMs) and prepayment penalties, and did not require full documentation of income—all<br />

characteristics that are commonly associated with “predatory lending.” These loans also had<br />

been defaulting at very high rates (more than 20% of subprime loans originated in HB4050 zip<br />

codes in the year prior to the pilot defaulted within their first 18 months). Thus, to the extent that<br />

HB4050 made it more difficult for this subset of lenders to originate such loans with high ex post<br />

default rates, we regard the pilot as an exogenous shock to lending practices with potentially<br />

predatory characteristics.<br />

Our empirical analysis is based on the idea that HB4050 did not have a material effect in<br />

untreated but similar areas. If predatory lending leads to higher default rates, we would expect<br />

the negative exogenous shock to such lending practices to have a sizable effect on loan<br />

performance.<br />

Another way to think about the proposed empirical design is as a two-stage analysis. In<br />

the first stage, we verify that the legislation had a material effect on mortgage origination<br />

15


practices in the treated area. For example, we show that in the treated area the fraction of “highrisk”<br />

mortgages declined significantly, as did the overall volume of originations and the number<br />

of active lenders.<br />

The second stage of the analysis measures the effect of the shock to the lending market<br />

on mortgage performance. This stage is based on cross-sectional and temporal variation in a<br />

difference-in-differences framework. Specifically, our tests measure the difference in the<br />

response of various variables (e.g., default status, contract choice, etc.) as a function of whether<br />

the loan was originated in a zip code subject to HB4050. Our regressions include both time<br />

controls and cross-sectional controls, as in classic difference-in-differences analysis.<br />

Our basic regression specifications have the following form:<br />

Response ijt = α + β Treatment jt + γ Time dummies t + δ Zip dummies j + θ Controls ijt + ε ijt , (1)<br />

where Response ijt is the loan-level response variable, such as default status of loan i originated at<br />

time t in zip j; Treatment jt is a dummy variable that receives a value of one if zip code j is subject<br />

to mandatory counseling in month t and the loan is originated by a state-licensed lender, and 0<br />

otherwise; and Time and Zip dummies capture fixed time and location effects, respectively. In all<br />

regressions, we cluster errors at the zip code level. 19 For each loan, the response is evaluated at<br />

only one point in time (e.g., interest rate at origination or default status 18 months thereafter).<br />

Consequently, our data set is made up of a series of monthly cross-sections. The set of controls<br />

varies with the underlying data source, but it includes variables such as LTV at origination,<br />

borrower FICO score, loan interest rate, and so forth.<br />

3.5. Discussion of the Exclusion Restriction and the Context of the Estimates<br />

Our empirical tests provide estimates of the effect of the anti-predatory program on the<br />

performance of loans. Here we discuss whether our estimates of improved mortgage<br />

19 Clustering allows for an arbitrary covariance structure of error terms over time within each zip code and, thus,<br />

adjusts standard error estimates for serial correlation, potentially correcting a serious inference problem (Bertrand,<br />

Duflo, and Mullainathan, 2004). Depending on the sample, there are 22 or 53 zip codes in our regressions.<br />

16


performance can be attributed to the reduction in predatory lending and whether the result can be<br />

generalized to the entire national market. We identify the effect of predatory lending on borrower<br />

default based on the assumption that HB4050 affected default rates only through its impact on<br />

predatory lending (the exclusion restriction). This assumption may not hold for two main<br />

reasons: (1) the legislation is likely to have altered additional aspects of borrower decision<br />

making, and (2) the legislation is likely to have induced spillovers of borrowers and lenders from<br />

the treated zip codes into neighboring zip codes. Below, we analyze the potential effects of<br />

violating the exclusion restriction assumption.<br />

The anti-predatory program affected the performance of loans through two main<br />

channels: oversight and education. First, the program imposed oversight on lenders by subjecting<br />

their loan offers to external review, thus causing predatory lenders to be more cautious. Second,<br />

the program provided a detailed review to borrowers, which could have improved their decision<br />

making. During the 20 weeks in which the pilot program took place, over 1,200 borrowers<br />

received information about mortgages. In our sample of 191 loans, about 19% did not pursue<br />

their loan application following the counseling and another 40% modified some of the mortgage<br />

characteristics. Although it is difficult to clearly distinguish between the channels, our<br />

measurement of the effect of predatory lending relies on the direct effect of the program through<br />

oversight. It is plausible, however, that the indirect channel of education violates the exclusion<br />

restriction and that some of the effect of the anti-predatory program on default rates came<br />

through this indirect channel.<br />

Moreover, spillovers of loans from the treatment sample to the control sample violate the<br />

exclusion restriction because they may have adversely affected the quality of loans originated in<br />

the control sample. Such spillovers could have happened along three dimensions: spatial, crosssectional,<br />

and temporal. First, potential purchasers could have moved from the treated area to<br />

surrounding areas (most likely to the control zip codes, as they have similar characteristics).<br />

Figure 2a presents the volume of applications in the treated zip codes and the control sample zip<br />

codes, per state-licensed lenders (treated) and non-state-licensed lenders (not treated). Figure 2b<br />

17


presents similar analysis for originated mortgages. The figures show no apparent spillover in<br />

volume. Second, borrowers could have shifted to lenders in the treated area that were not subject<br />

to the legislation, i.e., non-state-chartered lenders. However, again Figures 2a and 2b do not<br />

show evidence of such a move. One possible explanation for the lack of spillover is that the<br />

market was segmented and state-licensed lenders and non-state-licensed lenders serviced<br />

different populations (subprime and prime borrowers, respectively). Third, there is the possibility<br />

of a run-up in mortgage applications in the treated area before the starting date of the program<br />

(which was known in advance). Figures 2a and 2b do suggest some buildup in applications and<br />

approvals before the onset of HB4050. They also show a minor tick-up immediately after the<br />

termination of the program, in March 2007. Potentially this is a spillover effect, and these loans<br />

could have been originated during the legislation period.<br />

We argue that both violations of the exclusion restriction assumption cause our estimates<br />

of the effect of predatory lending on borrower default rates to be overstated. If the program<br />

affected default rates through the education channel, then we cannot ascribe the entire measured<br />

effect to the elimination of predatory lending. Further, if there were spillovers, then the credit<br />

quality of the control group is worse than it would be otherwise, creating a greater spread in<br />

default rates between the treated and control groups.<br />

In a similar vein, it is likely that the legislation had an effect not only on predatory<br />

lending, but also on merely “aggressive” lending practices that pushed the boundaries of legally<br />

permissible behavior without violating them. In this case, the effect that we attribute to predatory<br />

lending should be ascribed to both predatory and aggressive lending practices. With the<br />

exception of our analysis in Section 6, distinguishing between the two types of practices is<br />

difficult. Nevertheless, this limitation also bounds our results from above. Even if we overstate<br />

the number of predatory loans eliminated by the pilot, our results show that the effect on default<br />

rates is relatively small.<br />

A second issue is whether the effects of predatory lending measured in the context of the<br />

HB4050 legislation can be extrapolated to the national level. There are several reasons to be<br />

18


skeptical of this. The treatment area was characterized by high delinquency rates due,<br />

supposedly, to predatory lending. This lending was done by a particular subset of financial<br />

intermediaries who were readily identifiable and subject to state regulation. The penalties for<br />

noncompliance were fairly harsh, partially because of lack of clarity regarding enforcement. All<br />

of these factors are unlikely to hold for the country as a whole, limiting the effect of such<br />

regulatory intervention. Furthermore, the limited geographic scope of HB4050 made it relatively<br />

easy for lenders to exit, whether because of high compliance costs or for the strategic goal of<br />

highlighting the contractionary effects of the pilot on credit availability. This amplified the effect<br />

of the pilot but would not be applicable at the national level. For all of these reasons, it is likely<br />

that our estimates are an upper bound for the effect of predatory lending.<br />

4. The Effects of HB4050 on <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong><br />

As described above, the legislation disrupted mortgage markets by changing the loan<br />

origination process for certain borrowers and products. This section empirically evaluates its<br />

effect on loan volumes, borrower and mortgage characteristics, and lender participation.<br />

4.1. Impact of the Legislation on Application and Mortgage Volumes<br />

We measure mortgage market activity by the volume of loan applications and loan<br />

originations captured in the HMDA database. 20 Figure 2a depicts the total number of loan<br />

applications in the treated zip codes (the solid line) and in the control zip codes (the dashed line).<br />

This information is reported in two panels that further subdivide applications reported by statelicensed<br />

lenders (who are subject to the legislation) and all other lenders (labeled exempt).<br />

There is a precipitous decline in loan applications among state-licensed mortgage lenders<br />

in HB4050 zip codes around the time the regulation became effective (September 1, 2006). For<br />

these lenders, the application volume dropped from 5,276 in August 2006 to 3,584 in September<br />

20 We count all relevant HMDA records that have one of the following action codes: originated, denied, approved<br />

but not taken, withdrawn, or incomplete.<br />

19


(32% decline), and to 2,275 in October. We observe some run-up in applications in the treated<br />

areas prior to the legislation period, though it is much smaller than the subsequent drop. In<br />

contrast, application levels in control zip codes hold steady through December 2006. Following<br />

the repeal of HB4050, activity levels in both control and treatment areas converged nearly<br />

instantaneously; then they plummeted jointly to about half that of the market heyday. For nonstate-licensed<br />

lenders (chart on the right), we observe no differential effect in the HB4050 and<br />

control zip codes throughout the period examined.<br />

We observe similarly striking evidence when examining mortgage originations. In Figure<br />

2b, the left chart shows mortgage originations for state-licensed lenders. Originations in HB4050<br />

zip codes collapsed from 2,046 in August 2006 to 785 in September 2006 (a 62% decline) and<br />

remained at this depressed level until the end of 2006. Their levels completely converged with<br />

originations in the control zip codes following the termination of the program in February 2007,<br />

by which time subprime lending activity was grinding to a halt nationwide. Again, we do not<br />

observe any effects of the legislation for non-state-licensed lenders in either the HB4050 or the<br />

control zip codes.<br />

Table 2 presents the triple difference (diff-in-diff-in-diff) analysis of the drop in activity,<br />

as captured by the HMDA data. We calculate the difference between the number of applications<br />

before and during the legislation period in HB4050 and control zip codes among state-licensed<br />

lenders. We then repeat the same calculation for non-state-licensed lenders and calculate the<br />

difference in the results between the two lender subsets. Panel A focuses on changes in the<br />

monthly rate of applications. It shows a substantial decline in the treated zip codes relative to the<br />

controls among state-licensed lenders: 51% versus 14%. In contrast, there is no measurable<br />

difference in the number of applications to non-state-licensed lenders, which increased<br />

marginally during the pilot period in both the treated and the control areas. Consequently, the<br />

difference between changes in treatment and control applications for state-licensed and nonstate-licensed<br />

lenders is striking at nearly 29%. This leads us to conclude that HB4050<br />

20


significantly lowered borrower applications for mortgage credit and that its impact was, in fact,<br />

concentrated among state-licensed lenders.<br />

Next, we use the same method to estimate relative changes in origination activity. As<br />

shown in Table 2, Panel B, we find a decrease of 61% in the total number of mortgage<br />

originations by state-licensed lenders in HB4050 zip codes, with a 68% decline in purchase<br />

mortgages and a 54% decline in mortgage refinance transactions. As with applications, the drop<br />

in originations by state-licensed lenders in control zip codes is much smaller. Although there is a<br />

marginal rise in originations by non-state-licensed lenders, the increase is far too small to<br />

compensate for losses in credit origination by state-licensed lenders. Overall, the difference in<br />

the relative decline in total originations by state-licensed lenders in the treatment area and time<br />

period amounted to 39%. This further underscores our contention that the two sets of lenders<br />

served different segments of the market.<br />

In preparation for the default analysis that follows, we also perform a robustness check of<br />

these results based on the matched sample between the LP data set (which contains default<br />

information) and the HMDA data. The results are reported in Panel C, and they follow exactly<br />

the same pattern. The magnitude of the declines, both relative and absolute, is even stronger in<br />

the matched sample, which is heavily tilted towards state-licensed lenders that originated<br />

subprime loans. For example, the panel shows a 67% drop in originations among such lenders in<br />

treated zip codes, relative to a 14% runoff in the control area.<br />

We also note that the effect of the legislation is more pronounced for refinancing<br />

transactions relative to purchase mortgages. This result is consistent with Choi (2011), who<br />

examines the effect of anti-predatory legislation on origination volumes and finds a small effect<br />

for purchase mortgages and a larger effect for refinancing mortgages. There are two potential<br />

explanations for this result. First, refinancing activity is often discretionary. In particular,<br />

borrowers who refinance a loan can often wait or find alternative sources of financing. For<br />

purchases, however, if a buyer wants to complete the transaction, she usually has to take out a<br />

mortgage in a timely manner. Second, the HB4050 legislation specified frequent refinancing<br />

21


transactions as one of the triggers for identifying risky mortgages that would require counseling.<br />

Therefore, one would expect a greater decline in refinancing transactions.<br />

In sum, the results show that the legislation had far-reaching effects on the volumes of<br />

mortgage applications and originated loans. Moreover, these effects were most pronounced in the<br />

targeted population—state-licensed lenders originating loans for low-FICO-score borrowers.<br />

4.2. Differential Impact of the Legislation by Borrower and Mortgage Characteristics<br />

Given that the legislation had a significant effect on mortgage originations, we examine<br />

whether there was a change in the composition of borrower and mortgage types during the<br />

treatment period. After all, the pilot effectively increased the cost of originating mortgages to<br />

low-credit-quality borrowers as well as the cost of originating what were considered risky loans.<br />

To explore this issue, we use a sample including all mortgages in the LP-HMDA data set<br />

that were originated in the treatment and control zip codes between 2005 and 2007. The<br />

dependent variables are borrower and mortgage characteristics. The independent variable of<br />

interest is the interaction between the HB4050 dummy and the state-licensed lender dummy,<br />

which takes a value of one if the loan was originated subject to the HB4050 legislation. The<br />

regressions include month fixed effects interacted with a state-licensed dummy and zip code<br />

fixed effects interacted with the state-licensed dummy. This specification assures that there are<br />

fixed effects for each dimension that is differenced out (time, zip code, and type of lender).<br />

Standard errors are clustered by zip code to account for correlation within geographical areas.<br />

The regression results in Table 3, Panel A show that the composition of borrowers and<br />

mortgage types changed significantly following the legislation. Column (1) indicates the average<br />

FICO score of loans originated in the treated zip codes during the HB4050 period was 7.8 points<br />

higher. This result is material as it reflects a shift of 0.13 standard deviations in the distribution<br />

of borrowers (see Table 1, Panel B). Column (2) shows further evidence that the credit quality of<br />

borrowers increased: the average interest spread declined by 0.43 percentage points—or 0.43<br />

22


standard deviations. Overall, this evidence suggests that during the treatment period, the<br />

population of borrowers was of appreciably better credit quality.<br />

We also observe that the originated mortgages are less likely to fall into risky categories<br />

as defined by HB4050. In Columns (3) to (8), we examine the change in a variety of mortgage<br />

characteristics: whether loans are adjustable rate mortgages, have low documentation, are<br />

classified as risky mortgages by the HB4050 regulation (Category I or Category II), or are 100%<br />

loan-to-value (LTV), and whether loans are considered “excessively risky” (i.e., mortgages that<br />

are ARM, no- or low-documentation, interest only, and ≥95% LTV).<br />

The regressions show that mortgages originated in the treated areas would be considered<br />

less risky by the legislation on most dimensions. Following implementation of HB4050, ARM<br />

originations declined by 5.2% (t = 2.60; where the base rate in the control sample is 76%),<br />

Category I loans declined by 2.6% (t = 1.53; the base rate is 83%), Category II loans declined by<br />

3.9% (t = 2.78; the base rate is 20%), 100% LTV loans declined by 2.5% (t = 1.39; the base rate<br />

is 16%), and excessive loans declined by 2.2% (t = 2.00; the base rate is 10%). We do not detect<br />

a decline in no- and low-documentation loans.<br />

In Panel B we perform a robustness test for the above results. Here we restrict the sample<br />

to lenders who did not exit from the HB4050 zip codes during the legislation period. As<br />

described in greater detail below, we define the “exit group” as lenders who reduced their<br />

average monthly lending rate by more than 90% relative to the prepilot period. The results show<br />

that the change in the composition of borrowers and products was independent of lender exit,<br />

i.e., the quality of borrowers and loans also increased for the remaining lenders.<br />

Overall, these findings show that new borrowers in the treated group were of better credit<br />

quality and the originated loans were materially less risky, as defined by the legislation, than<br />

those in the control group.<br />

23


4.3. Impact of the Legislation on Lender Exit<br />

Part of the dramatic drop in loan applications can be traced to a number of muchpublicized<br />

lender withdrawals from the market. We tackle the question of market exit by<br />

counting the number of unique lenders filing HMDA reports before, during, and after the<br />

treatment period in both the treated and control zip codes. To be counted as an active lender in a<br />

given geographic area, a HMDA-reporting institution must originate at least 10% of its prepilot<br />

average per month during the pilot period, with at least one origination in every month. 21 Panel A<br />

of Table 4 summarizes the results of this exercise. Of the 89 active state-licensed lenders in the<br />

treated zip codes in the prelegislative period (January 2005–August 2006), only 46 continued to<br />

lend during the treatment period. In a reprise of mortgage origination results, the decline in the<br />

number of lenders is much greater in the treatment areas, and exit is concentrated among statelicensed<br />

lenders.<br />

As noted before, the legislation created some legal uncertainty about the enforceability of<br />

mortgage contracts in the treated zip codes. This ambiguity by itself may have accounted for the<br />

strong lender response along the extensive margin. It is also conceivable that exit from HB4050<br />

areas was a strategic response by lenders determined to emphasize the disruptive nature of this<br />

high-profile regulation.<br />

We explore the characteristics of exiting lenders in Panel B of Table 4. Because we want<br />

to focus on mortgage contract features and performance, we need to work with the LP-HMDA<br />

data set, which contains fewer lenders. The sample includes 55 lenders that were active in the<br />

HB4050 zip codes during the prepilot period (January 2005–August 2006). The majority of these<br />

lenders (43) were state-licensed. We focus on loans originated during calendar year 2005, when<br />

HB4050 discussions were not prevalent.<br />

We note that exiting lenders were smaller. They originated mortgages to borrowers with<br />

somewhat lower credit scores but charged a slightly lower credit spread. A higher share of those<br />

21 None of the patterns depend on the choice of the threshold level or geographic area. The “every month” condition<br />

is intended to eliminate lenders that withdrew from HB4050 zip codes during the fall of 2006 after working off their<br />

backlog of earlier applications.<br />

24


mortgages had adjustable-rate contracts. They originated a higher share of Category I and II<br />

loans, but a lower fraction of their loans had no equity (100% LTV). Yet, on net, the 18-month<br />

default rate on mortgages originated in 2005 is measurably higher for state-licensed lenders that<br />

ended up exiting HB4050 areas—11.6% versus 10.4% for lenders that continued operating. We<br />

also note that non-state-licensed lenders in the LP-HMDA sample appear to have had very low<br />

lending volumes and to have been serving a much higher credit quality population.<br />

Overall, our results show state-licensed lenders were more likely to exit the HB4050 zip<br />

codes during the legislation period. These lenders appear to have served a population with lower<br />

credit quality and to have provided loans that were categorized by regulators as risky.<br />

5. The Effect of the Anti-<strong>Predatory</strong> Program on Default Rates<br />

The previous sections established that the legislation reduced market activity in general,<br />

and in particular, improved the average credit quality of borrowers, improved the risk profile of<br />

mortgages, and affected lenders that originated risky loans. From the point of view of the<br />

legislators, these effects are in line with their objective—to reduce what was perceived to be<br />

predatory lending activity.<br />

Given these changes in the market, we now examine the effects of the legislation on<br />

mortgage performance. The hypothesis that we test is whether lower predatory lending activity<br />

had a material effect on mortgage default. We measure loan performance by flagging borrowers<br />

who defaulted on their loans within 18 months of origination. 22 We then estimate a series of<br />

ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions, as defined in equation (1), in which the set of controls<br />

includes measures of borrower credit quality (FICO score), contract terms (LTV ratio, interest<br />

spread, and logged property valuation), and contract type (no- or low-documentation, and<br />

indicators for Categories I and II). In addition, we include three sets of fixed effects: month<br />

dummies interacted with a state-licensed lender indicator, zip code dummies interacted with a<br />

22 A loan is considered defaulted if it is 90+ days past due, in bankruptcy, or in foreclosure or is real-estate owned by<br />

the lender.<br />

25


state-licensed lender indicator, and zip code interacted with calendar month. These fixed effects<br />

control for variation in all three dimensions that define the treatment: zip code, month, and<br />

lender type.<br />

We present two sets of base regressions in Table 5, Panels A and B. Panel A uses a<br />

sample based on all mortgages between 2005 and 2007 originated in the pilot zip codes in<br />

addition to mortgages in the 12–zip code control group. Panel B uses the same treatment group<br />

but uses the synthetic control sample of matched loans (as defined in Section 3.3). The<br />

dependent variable in all regressions is an indicator of loan default within 18 months. In all<br />

regressions, the variable of interest is an indicator of whether the loan is part of the treatment<br />

group (i.e., originated by a state-licensed lender during the pilot period in the pilot zip codes).<br />

In each panel, there are six regression specifications. In Column (1) in each panel, we<br />

include no controls other than the fixed effects described above. In Column (2), we add controls<br />

for FICO score and logged loan amount. In Column (3), we add the no/low documentation<br />

indicator, indicators of whether the loans fall under Category I or Category II, and the LTV<br />

variable. Columns (4) to (6) repeat the specifications of Columns (1) to (3) but add lender fixed<br />

effects.<br />

The results in Table 5, Panels A and B show that when we consider the entire treated<br />

group, the effects of the legislation on default rates are virtually nonexistent. In Panel A, there is<br />

no discernible effect. In Panel B, the effect on the treatment loans is negative, but it is<br />

economically small and statistically insignificant. The magnitude of legislation-related declines<br />

in default rates is about 1 percentage point (no lender fixed effects) or about 2.5 percentage<br />

points (with lender fixed effects). The unconditional likelihood of default in the loan-matched<br />

control sample during the pilot time is 23.8%; hence, the legislation caused a decline in default<br />

of up to 11% for the treated group.<br />

In Panels C and D, we present additional specifications of the baseline regressions to<br />

hone down on drivers of default in different subsamples, focusing on subgroups that are likely to<br />

exhibit stronger results. Panel C uses a control sample that is based on the 12 control zip codes,<br />

26


while Panel D is based on the matched synthetic sample. In the first specification, the sample<br />

includes only subprime borrowers (FICO ≤ 620). In the second specification, the sample is<br />

restricted to loans originated by state-licensed lenders. The third specification includes only<br />

loans made to subprime borrowers by state-licensed lenders. The fourth specification is restricted<br />

even further to state lenders who did not exit from the sample.<br />

Comparing the results in the different specifications sheds light on the source of the<br />

decline in default rates. Specifically, the decline in the default rate is steepest in the matched<br />

synthetic sample that is restricted to the subprime population and state-licensed lenders. It is also<br />

the only sample in which the improvement in default rates is statistically significant. For this<br />

population, the decline in default is about 6 to 7 percentage points, out of a base rate of about<br />

27.2% (third specification in Panel D). This means that the improvement in mortgage<br />

performance is concentrated in the subprime population.<br />

To answer the question of whether the decline in default is due to the exit of predatory<br />

lenders, we compare the third and fourth specifications. The samples used in these specifications<br />

are the same except that the latter is limited to lenders that continued lending in the treatment zip<br />

codes during the pilot period. The regressions show that the decline in default dissipates once<br />

this restriction is imposed. Put differently, we observe no improvement in the performance of<br />

subprime loans originated by lenders that continued to operate in HB4050 zip codes during the<br />

pilot period. The juxtaposition of these results leads us to conclude that the decline in default was<br />

driven by lender exit.<br />

In Panel E, we provide additional specifications for robustness purposes. The dependent<br />

variable in these regressions is an indicator of whether the loan defaulted within 36 months (as<br />

opposed to 18 months earlier). The motivation for this is to verify that our results are not driven<br />

by a difference in the sensitivity of the explored populations to the financial crisis; a period of 36<br />

months extends well into the crisis period. Then, we rerun the third and fourth specifications<br />

from Panels C and D. The results show that that the decline in default mirrors the panels above.<br />

27


To summarize, our results show that the overall effect of the legislation on mortgage<br />

default rates in treated areas was relatively minor: a decline of 1 to 2.5 percentage points, for a<br />

base rate default of 24 to 27 percent. We find, however, that the pilot had a stronger effect on the<br />

subprime population, for whom the improvement in default rates was statistically and<br />

economically significant: between 5 and 7 percentage points, for a base rate of default of 27%<br />

(18% to 26% relative decline). Furthermore, our evidence shows that the decline in defaults was<br />

driven by lender exit. Hence, these findings suggest the withdrawal from the market of some<br />

lenders resulted in a measurable improvement in loan performance for those subprime borrowers<br />

who were able to access the credit market.<br />

6. Estimating the Default Rate of <strong>Predatory</strong> Loans<br />

With estimates obtained in the preceding sections, we can calculate the default rate of<br />

“predatory” loans, after making some assumptions about loan distribution across markets. In this<br />

exercise, “predatory loans” are defined as loans that were not originated during the HB4050 pilot<br />

period, presumably because of the effect of the treatment. Our goal here is to approximate the<br />

hypothetical default rate of predatory loans.<br />

We estimate that the default rate on subprime loans that were not originated due to<br />

HB4050 would have been about 32 percent. We performed this algebraic calculation in the<br />

following manner: from Table 1, Panel B, we see the default rates in the treated and control<br />

samples were very similar both before and after the treatment period. It was only during the<br />

treatment period that they diverged. Thus, assuming they would have been similar without the<br />

treatment, we can back out the hypothetical default rate for the precluded predatory loans. In the<br />

synthetic control sample of state-licensed subprime loans, all originated loans during the<br />

treatment period had a default rate of 26.4 percent (Table 1, Panel B, Column (6)). In the treated<br />

group, loan activity declined by 53.7% (Table 2, Panel C, state-licensed lenders), and the default<br />

rate declined by about 7.0 percentage points (Table 5, Panel D, third specification, Columns (4)-<br />

(6)). Therefore, the “precluded” predatory loans would have required a default rate of 32.4% in<br />

28


order to reach an average default rate of 26.4%. 23 With this calculation, predatory loans appear to<br />

have a default rate 6.0 percentage points (32.4% – 26.4%) higher than loans that are not<br />

predatory.<br />

It is important to note that the pilot also disrupted mortgage activity outside of the<br />

narrowly defined subprime segment of the market. Those segments did not realize any gains<br />

from improved mortgage performance (e.g., Table 5, Panels A and B) but did experience the<br />

costs of the disruption.<br />

Because of the assumptions required for the above calculation, we utilize alternative data<br />

to test for robustness of this estimate using a different methodology. Specifically, we calculate<br />

the default rate of predatory loans using data provided by one of the HUD counseling agencies<br />

that collected loan and borrower information as part of the HB4050 mandate. Our sample<br />

includes 121 loans that we could match to loans in the LP data set.<br />

During the counseling process, the counselors flagged some loans as potentially being<br />

predatory. They used three main criteria in making this determination: the loan was priced above<br />

the market rates, the borrower was thought not to be able to afford the loan, and the loan was<br />

thought to have fraud indicia (Housing Action Illinois, 2007). We use these flags to measure the<br />

effect of predatory lending in two empirical settings.<br />

Our first test compares the performance of loans with predatory flags to those not<br />

identified as predatory. Table 6, Panel A shows the results. A loan flagged as predatory yet still<br />

originated had a 6.5 percentage points higher default rate (90+ days delinquent) within 18<br />

months (Column (1)). This magnitude is very similar to the above calculation of a 6.0 percentage<br />

point differential in default rates (although it is not statistically different from zero given our<br />

limited sample size). We also measure the probability of default of the subsample of loans that<br />

were flagged as having indicia of fraud (as opposed to using the three criteria discussed above).<br />

We find the default rate differential for these loans to be even higher at 12.3 percentage points<br />

(Column (3)).<br />

23 (26.4% - 7.0%) * (100% - 53.7%) + X * 53.7% = 26.4%; X = 32.4%.<br />

29


An additional question is whether counselors flagged loans as problematic based on<br />

readily observable information or whether they also relied on soft information collected during<br />

the counseling sessions. This question is relevant for policy design because if only observable<br />

information was used in making the predatory designation, the same outcome could have been<br />

achieved with a specific underwriting protocol and without counselor review.<br />

To tackle this question, we construct a sample of loans in the control zip codes that are<br />

matched to the 121 counseled loans for which we have contract and performance data.<br />

Specifically, we match each counseled loan with up to ten other loans in the control zip codes<br />

that were originated during the same time period, were originated for the same purpose<br />

(purchase/refinance), and had similar house prices, adjustable/fixed rate types, leverage,<br />

documentation levels, interest rates, and FICO scores. 24 Overall, our matched sample includes<br />

1,048 loans (summary statistics are provided in Table 1, Panel E). If a counseled loan is flagged,<br />

we give it a “red flag” indicator and similarly tag each of its matched control loans. Assuming<br />

that the predatory designation was given based on observables only, we would expect to continue<br />

to see higher default probabilities on all “red flag” loans but not to see any differential impact<br />

among the “red flag” loans that were actually counseled.<br />

Table 6, Panel B presents the regression results. Consistent with the previous evidence,<br />

the regression shows that the “red flag” loans have about a 6 percentage point higher default rate<br />

than nonflagged loans. The interaction with the counseling indicator suggests that the loans that<br />

were actually counseled are not materially different from those that were matched to them, which<br />

is consistent with the idea that loans were flagged based solely on observables.<br />

We repeat the same exercise with “red flag” defined as only cases of suspected fraud. The<br />

coefficient on the fraud red flag and its interaction with the counseling indicator (Columns (3)-<br />

(4)) are positive but very imprecisely estimated. This finding suggests that our loan-matching<br />

procedure did not match well on the fraud dimension—most likely because indicia of fraud are<br />

24 More precisely, we include loans that were originated within 31 days of one another and that had house prices<br />

within $8,000, leverage within 10%, interest rates within 1%, and FICO scores within 20 points.<br />

30


ased on soft information collected by counselors that is unobservable in the raw mortgage<br />

servicer data. The results in Panel B indicate that some dimensions of predatory lending, such as<br />

loan affordability and excessive interest rates, are readily captured with observable data, while<br />

others such as fraud indicia are not.<br />

To summarize, this section used multiple methods to measure the default rates of<br />

predatory loans. The different methods generated strikingly similar estimates: predatory loans<br />

originated in this period had an 18-month default rate that was about 6 percentage points higher<br />

than similar loans that were not predatory.<br />

7. Conclusion<br />

Whether predatory lending was an important factor in precipitating the subprime crisis is<br />

one of the key questions in the academic and policy debate about the sources of the crisis and its<br />

aftermath. The main empirical challenge in answering this question is that it is difficult to<br />

distinguish predatory loans from nonpredatory loans on an ex ante basis. In general, predatory<br />

lenders exploit borrowers by having an informational advantage over them. This informational<br />

advantage is not easily discernible when examining the observable characteristics alone.<br />

In this study we use an anti-predatory legislative pilot (HB4050) enacted in 2006 in<br />

Chicago as an instrument for identifying predatory lending. The legislation required certain<br />

borrowers in ten zip codes in Chicago to seek counseling when they took out a mortgage from<br />

state-licensed lenders. Following implementation of the pilot, market activity dropped by about<br />

40%, largely through the exit of lenders specializing in risky loans and through a decline in the<br />

share of subprime borrowers. Default rates in the subpopulation targeted by the pilot—subprime<br />

borrowers served by state-licensed lenders—improved by 6 to 7 percentage points, relative to the<br />

unconditional default rate of 26 percent. We use these estimates to impute a hypothetical default<br />

rate of about 32 percent on the presumably predatory loans that were not originated due to<br />

HB4050. We obtain similar estimates using other techniques based on subsamples of loans that<br />

were counseled and flagged as being predatory.<br />

31


In interpreting our results, the first thing to note is that the pilot represented a very blunt<br />

policy tool. Its bluntness reflects the severe informational problems that exist in identifying<br />

predatory lending. <strong>Predatory</strong> lending is about unobservable information: lenders engage in<br />

predatory lending when they exploit borrowers by having superior information about their ability<br />

to repay the loan (Bond, Musto, and Yilmaz, 2009). Given the ambiguity and subjectivity in<br />

identifying which loans are predatory and which are not, regulators must resort to rough proxies<br />

(Litan, 2001). In the case of HB4050, predatory loans were proxied as loans made in the poorer<br />

parts of the city to borrowers with low credit scores and with a certain risk profile. Of course,<br />

these proxies are imperfect and therefore may impose costs on lenders who do not make<br />

predatory loans and on borrowers who are not being exploited.<br />

The bluntness of HB4050 resulted in severe market disruptions, as it drove about half of<br />

the state-licensed lenders out of the market, lowered the number of originated mortgages by<br />

about a third, and imposed high counseling costs on the remaining borrowers and lenders. The<br />

wide and fairly indiscriminate reach of the pilot also triggered intense public opposition from all<br />

of the affected parties—communities and lenders alike—ultimately leading to its early<br />

termination. This response highlights the political difficulties involved in policy interventions in<br />

an environment with inherently complex incentive structures and asymmetric information held<br />

by lenders, borrowers, and regulators.<br />

The pilot did appear to lower default rates among its primary target population—<br />

subprime borrowers served by state-licensed lenders. Although these improvements in mortgage<br />

performance were measurable, the default rates among the treated subset of borrowers remained<br />

alarmingly high. This suggests that potentially predatory lending practices by themselves cannot<br />

account for the meltdown in the subprime mortgage market.<br />

Our finding that eliminating bad lenders had a greater impact on mortgage defaults than<br />

eliminating bad loans also suggests that reckless, rather than predatory, lending practices deserve<br />

greater scrutiny. Although answering this question is beyond the scope of this paper, these results<br />

are consistent with recent research that highlights the role of long intermediation chains in<br />

32


mortgage origination leading up to the crisis. In particular, the majority of lenders subject to<br />

HB4050 were mortgage banks and brokers that securitized the lion’s share of their loans. Such<br />

lending practices have been found to be associated with aggressive misrepresentation of<br />

information throughout the mortgage origination and funding process and with subsequently<br />

higher defaults (Keys et al., 2010; Jiang, Nelson, and Vytlacil, 2012; Piskorski, Seru, and Witkin,<br />

2013). In a similar vein, our finding that borrowers often chose to pursue bad loans in spite of<br />

(justified) warnings from counselors brings up questions of the role played by the borrowers<br />

themselves. These results join the body of literature showing that reckless lending and<br />

borrowing, combined with distorted incentives of intermediaries, were at the heart of the<br />

subprime crisis (e.g., Ben-David, 2011; Agarwal and Ben-David, 2013).<br />

It may be tempting to conduct a back-of-the-envelope welfare analysis by linking the<br />

estimates of reductions in defaults with the costs of such defaults and of the counseling itself. 25<br />

However, doing so fails to take into account a number of important effects—losses in utility<br />

incurred by excluded borrowers, positive spillovers on neighborhood property values from lower<br />

defaults, losses from inefficient contract choices that resulted from trying to avoid counseling<br />

sessions, and so forth. Moreover, evaluating the overall welfare effect of this intervention<br />

requires weighing the relative costs and benefits accruing to different market participants. 26 It is<br />

further complicated by various distortions that already exist in the housing market due to unique<br />

tax treatment, zoning restrictions, and so forth, as well as potential externalities produced by<br />

individual housing decisions.<br />

25 For instance, we could have taken the average house value in HB4050 zip codes of $190,000 and assumed a<br />

deadweight loss from foreclosure of about 30% (Campbell, Giglio, and Pathak, 2011). Based on the estimate of a<br />

6% higher default rate resulting from predatory lending, the expected benefit from curbing predatory lending would<br />

be $3,420 (0.06*$190,000*30%) per borrower. Therefore, the pre-borrower net direct benefit (net of counseling fee<br />

and approximately $100 for the cost of time) would be of approximately $2,000.<br />

26 Some recent attempts to theoretically model the welfare effects of policy choices in household financial markets<br />

include Carlin and Gervais (2009); Bolton, Freixas, and Shapiro (2007); and Carlin (2009).<br />

33


Mandated financial counseling and increased oversight of lenders are important policy<br />

tools being considered in the wake of the housing market crisis. 27<br />

Both policies impose<br />

restrictions on free contracting between borrowers and lenders. As such, they can be expected to<br />

shrink credit markets, particularly for the financially disadvantaged segments of the population.<br />

In addition to providing an estimate of the quantitative impact of anti-predatory-lending<br />

programs, our paper sounds a cautionary note about the difficulties of implementing effective<br />

policy in an informationally opaque setting with complex and conflicting incentives.<br />

27 In 2010 Congress passed the Dodd-Frank Act, which created a new Consumer Financial Protection Bureau<br />

(CFPB) to safeguard consumers from unfair, deceptive, and abusive practices in the financial sector. Among other<br />

approaches, CFPB is likely to consider increasing access to financial counseling.<br />

34


References<br />

Abadie, A., Gardeazabal, J., 2003. The economic costs of conflict: A case study of the Basque<br />

country. American Economic Review 93(1), 113-132.<br />

Agarwal, S., Evanoff, D. 2013. Do lenders steer borrowers to high risk mortgage products.<br />

Working paper. National University of Singapore.<br />

Agarwal, S., Amromin, G., Ben-David, I., Chomsisengphet, S., Evanoff, D., 2010. Learning to<br />

cope: Voluntary financial education programs and the housing crisis. American Economic<br />

Review 100(2), 495-500.<br />

Agarwal, S., Amromin, G., Ben-David, I., Chomsisengphet, S., Evanoff, D., 2012. The effects of<br />

financial education on household financial decision making: Evidence from a natural<br />

experiment of mortgage advice. Working paper. The Ohio State University.<br />

Agarwal, S., Ben-David, I., 2013. Do loan officers’ incentives lead to lax lending standards?<br />

Working paper. The Ohio State University.<br />

Agarwal, S., Skiba, P., Tobacman, J., 2009. Payday loans and credit cards: New liquidity and<br />

credit scoring puzzles? American Economic Review 99(2), 412-417.<br />

Bates, L.K., Van Zandt, S., 2007. Illinois’ new approach to regulating predatory lending:<br />

unintended consequences of borrower triggers and spatial targeting. Spatial Policy Analysis<br />

Research Consortium working paper 2007-02. University of Illinois.<br />

Ben-David, I., 2011. Financial constraints and inflated home prices during the real-estate boom.<br />

American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 102(3), 559-578.<br />

Ben-David, I., 2012. High leverage and high prices: Evidence from the residential real-estate<br />

market. Working paper. The Ohio State University.<br />

Bertrand, M., Duflo, E., Mullainathan, S., 2004. How much should we trust difference in<br />

differences estimates? Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(1), 249-275.<br />

Bertrand, M., Morse, M., 2011. Information disclosure, cognitive biases and payday borrowing.<br />

Journal of Finance 66(6), 1865-1893.<br />

Bolton, P., Freixas, X., Shapiro, J., 2007. Conflicts of interest, information provision, and<br />

competition in the financial services industry. Journal of Financial Economics 85(2), 297-<br />

330.<br />

Bond, P., Musto, D.K., Yilmaz, B., 2009. <strong>Predatory</strong> mortgage lending. Journal of Financial<br />

Economics 94, 412-427.<br />

Bostic, R.W., Chomsisengphet, S., Engel, K.C., McCoy, P.A., Pennington-Cross, A., Wachter,<br />

S., 2012. Mortgage product substitution and state anti-predatory lending laws: Better loans<br />

and better borrowers? Atlantic Economic Journal 40(3), 273-294.<br />

Campbell, J.Y., Cocco, J.F., 2003. Household risk management and optimal mortgage choice.<br />

Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(4), 1449-1494.<br />

Campbell, J.Y., Giglio, S., Pathak, P., 2011. Forced sales and house prices. American Economic<br />

Review 101(5), 2108-2131.<br />

35


Carlin, B., 2009. Strategic price complexity in retail financial markets. Journal of Financial<br />

Economics 91(3), 278-287.<br />

Carlin, B., Gervais, S., 2009. Legal protection in retail financial markets. NBER working paper<br />

#14972.<br />

Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>, 2009. Restoring integrity to the financial system predatory<br />

lending and the economic crisis. Faith and Credit Issue Guide, September.<br />

Choi, H-S., 2011. The impact of anti-predatory lending laws on mortgage volume. Working<br />

paper. Princeton University.<br />

Engel, K.C., McCoy, P.A., 2007. Turning a blind eye: Wall Street finance of predatory <strong>Lending</strong>.<br />

Fordam Law Review 75, 101-165.<br />

Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), 2006. Challenges and FDIC efforts related to<br />

predatory lending. Report by the Office of Inspector General,<br />

http://www.fdicoig.gov/reports06/06-011.pdf<br />

Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, 2010. Final report of the National Commission on the<br />

Causes of the Financial and Economic Crisis in the United States. Internal report.<br />

Jiang, W., Nelson, A., Vytlacil. E., 2012. Liar's loan? Effects of origination channel and<br />

information falsification on mortgage delinquency. Review of Economics and Statistics<br />

(forthcoming).<br />

Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., Zingales, L., 2013. The determinants of attitudes towards strategic<br />

default on mortgages. Journal of Finance 68(4), 1473-1515.<br />

Housing Action Illinois, 2007. Findings from the HB4050 <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> Database Pilot<br />

Program.<br />

Hudson, M.W., 2010. The Monster: How a Gang of <strong>Predatory</strong> Lenders and Wall Street Bankers<br />

Fleeced America—and Spawned a Global Crisis. Macmillan, New York.<br />

Keys, B.J., Mukherjee, T., Seru, A., Vig, V., 2010. Did securitization lead to lax screening?<br />

Evidence from subprime loans. Quarterly Journal of Economics 125(1), 307-362.<br />

Litan, R.E., 2001. A prudent approach to preventing “predatory” lending. Report by The<br />

American Bankers Association.<br />

Melzer, B., 2011. The real costs of credit access: Evidence from the payday lending market.<br />

Quarterly Journal of Economics 126(1), 517-555.<br />

Morse, A., 2011. Payday lenders: Heroes or villains? Journal of Financial Economics 102(1), 28-<br />

44.<br />

Piskorski, T., Seru, A., Witkin, J., 2013. Asset quality misrepresentation by financial<br />

intermediaries: Evidence from RMBS market. NBER working paper #18843.<br />

Rajan, U., Seru, A., Vig, V., 2013. The failure of models that predict failure: Distance, incentives<br />

and defaults. Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming.<br />

U.S. Government Accountability Office (GAO), 2004. Consumer protection: Federal and state<br />

agencies face challenges in combating predatory lending. Report 04-280,<br />

http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d04280.pdf<br />

36


Yandle, B., 1983. Bootleggers and Baptists: The education of a regulatory economist. Regulation<br />

7(3), 12-16.<br />

Yandle, B., 1999. Bootleggers and Baptists in retrospect. Regulation 22(3), 5-7.<br />

37


Appendix. Media News around the Treatment Period<br />

The following list of articles reflects the public information and sentiment regarding the HB4050<br />

program. This list provides brief summaries of the articles.<br />

July 2005:<br />

- Governor Blagojevich signs House Bill 4050, which is designed to protects homebuyers from<br />

predatory lending in Cook County’s at-risk communities and reduce the incidence of<br />

foreclosures; the project is scheduled to begin January 1, 2006 (U.S. Fed News, July 21, 2005).<br />

- Mortgage brokers are concerned about the impact of the new legislation on origination business<br />

January 2006:<br />

(Origination News, July 1, 2005).<br />

- HB4050 is postponed due to technical and logistic issues (National Mortgage News, January 9,<br />

2006).<br />

March 2006:<br />

- Mortgage lenders object to HB4050 and argue that its compliance costs may prompt firms to<br />

August 2006:<br />

withdraw from the market (Chicago Tribune, March 19, 2006).<br />

- HB4050 goes into effect on September 1, 2006 (Chicago Tribune, August 20, 2006).<br />

September 2006:<br />

- “Mortgage pros fear new state regulations will hurt business” (Chicago Sun-Times, September<br />

11, 2006)<br />

- “Critics say counseling requirement amounts to redlining” (Chicago Tribune, September 18,<br />

2006)<br />

October 2006:<br />

- “State mortgage law backfires on most vulnerable homeowners” (Chicago Sun-Times, October 5,<br />

2006)<br />

- Governor Blagojevich advertises the “[HB4050] pilot program [as] providing borrowers with<br />

critical information on home loans and help[ing] state regulators and law enforcement track and<br />

crack down on dishonest lenders” (October 31, 2006).<br />

38


November 2006:<br />

- A group of residents and members of the real-estate community submit a lawsuit against the state<br />

claiming discrimination. (Chicago Tribune, November 2, 2006)<br />

- “Governor Blagojevich announces results of increased crackdown on unlicensed mortgage loan<br />

originators” (US Fed News, November 3, 2006)<br />

- The Coalition to Rescind HB4050 delivers petitions demanding amendments to HB4050<br />

(November 6). The Coalition is led by John Paul (president of the Greater Englewood Family<br />

Taskforce) and Julie Santos (an immigrants’ rights activist). They work towards the final veto<br />

session before the deadline of December 1, 2006.<br />

John Paul says, “We are calling our State officials to ‘Get on Board’ and ‘Get on FIRE’ working<br />

to rescind this discriminatory law and head-off declining property value.”<br />

Chicago mayoral candidate Dorothy Brown (supports the Coalition) says, “At issue is whether<br />

HR 4050, the state's pilot program designed to fight predatory lending practices, is meeting its<br />

objective or whether it is hurting the very people it is supposed to help... [HB4050] makes it<br />

harder for potential homeowners to get credit in those designated areas.” (South Street Journal,<br />

November 23, 2006)<br />

- “Neighborhood Housing Services (NHS) of Chicago, a nonprofit housing organization, and its<br />

lender partners are providing affordable financing to meet the needs of homebuyers and<br />

homeowners throughout Chicago and in the House Bill 4050 Pilot Program Area” (U.S.<br />

Newswire, November 6, 2006)<br />

- Critics say the counseling requirement is racist. Julie Santos (Coalition to Rescind HB4050) says<br />

that the law has made undocumented Hispanic immigrants afraid to buy homes because they<br />

hesitate to include their legal status in the state program's database. (Chicago Tribune, November<br />

14, 2006)<br />

- “Mortgage counseling law draws 2 nd suit.” The suit was filed by three consumers who say they<br />

have had difficulties buying, selling, or refinancing because of the law and one real-estate agent<br />

who reports a significant decline in business because of it, according to the federal complaint.<br />

(Chicago Tribune, November 16, 2006)<br />

- Mortgage brokers, realtors, home builders, and community groups agree about HB4050:<br />

“[HB4050] targets and stigmatizes primarily African American neighborhoods” (Chicago Sun-<br />

Times, November 17, 2006)<br />

- Under the direction of Governor Blagojevich, Secretary of Financial and Professional Regulation<br />

(IDFPR) Dean Martinez announces that he will hold a meeting with community leaders,<br />

legislators, homeowners, and real-estate professionals to discuss ways to improve the pilot<br />

39


program created by HB4050. (U.S. Fed News, November 20, 2006; Chicago Tribune, November<br />

28, 2006)<br />

December 2006:<br />

- Groups call the mortgage counseling law unfair and unnecessary. Jesse Jackson says the law<br />

imposes unnecessary burdens for those trying to buy and sell homes in those neighborhoods.<br />

(Chicago Sun-Times, December 24, 2006)<br />

January 2007:<br />

- “Governor Blagojevich shelves predatory-loan program.” Blagojevich releases the following<br />

statement: “Even though this law was designed to fight predatory loans, it is clear that the<br />

program may be negatively affecting the communities it is designed to protect.” (Chicago<br />

Tribune, January 20, 2007)<br />

- A study by the University of Illinois (Bates and Van Zandt, 2007) reports that home sales<br />

declined by 30% in the targeted areas relative to comparable areas. (Chicago Tribune, January 21,<br />

2007)<br />

March 2007:<br />

- The State of Illinois revises HB4050 so that it can be implemented throughout Cook County. The<br />

new program is targeted at first-time homebuyers. (Chicago Tribune, March 23, 2007)<br />

April 2007:<br />

- “Community groups argue that they are not sufficiently staffed for the new anti-predatory law”<br />

(Chicago Tribune, April 5, 2007)<br />

June 2007:<br />

- “Mortgage brokers oppose new anti-predatory lending program” (Home Equity Wire, June 15,<br />

2007)<br />

November 2007:<br />

- Governor Blagojevich signs the new anti-predatory bill protecting homebuyers from predatory<br />

lending. The project is scheduled to begin July 1, 2008. (Chicago Tribune, November 3, 2007)<br />

40


Table 1. Summary Statistics<br />

The table presents summary statistics for the data used in the study. Panel A compares demographics (from the 2005<br />

IRS Statistics of Income ZIP code data and 2000 Census) of the treated zip codes, the control zip codes, and the rest<br />

of Chicago. Panel B focuses on mortgages originated by state-licensed lenders; it compares means and standard<br />

deviations of the main variables used in the analysis across the treated zip codes, the control zip codes, and the<br />

matched loan (synthetic) sample, and across periods of time (pretreatment, during treatment, and post-treatment).<br />

Panel C presents similar statistics for non-state-licensed lenders. Panel D shows summary statistics (means and<br />

standard deviations) for non-state-licensed lenders. Panel E presents summary statistics for the variables in the data<br />

set received from a counseling agency, and for the matched sample for these loans.<br />

Panel A: Construction of a Control Sample on the Basis of Pretreatment Socioeconomic<br />

Characteristics (2005 IRS Statistics of Income ZIP code data and 2000 Census data)<br />

HB4050 zip codes Control zip codes Other Chicago zip codes<br />

(10 zip codes) (12 zip codes) (31 zip codes)<br />

Total population 729,980 713,155 1,467,491<br />

Total number of 2005 tax returns 259,884 244,326 642,281<br />

Share of minority households* 0.813 0.863 0.416<br />

Share of blacks 0.534 0.645 0.156<br />

Share of hispanics 0.282 0.222 0.263<br />

Share of households below poverty level* 0.200 0.245 0.163<br />

Average taxable income in 2005 # $31,579 $30,844 $66,004<br />

Share of households with income < $50,000 in 2005 0.843 0.850 0.714<br />

Unemployment rate (2000 Census)* 0.136 0.147 0.072<br />

Yearly change in house price index (HPI) (LP data)°<br />

2005 10.14% 8.92% 7.59%<br />

2006 2.36% 1.75% 3.73%<br />

2007 -7.47% -7.59% -4.57%<br />

For state-licensed loans originated in 1-12/2005:<br />

18-month default rate 0.151 0.150 0.089<br />

36-month default rate 0.276 0.251 0.170<br />

* population-weighted averages<br />

#<br />

weighted by number of 2005 IRS tax returns<br />

° weighted by number of households<br />

41


Panel B: State-Licensed Lenders<br />

Panel C: Non-State-Licensed Lenders<br />

Table 1. Summary Statistics (Cont.)<br />

Pre-treatment (1/2005-8/2006) Treatment Period (9/2006-1/2007) Post-treatment (2/2007-12/2007)<br />

HB 4050 Control Synthetic HB 4050 Control Synthetic HB 4050 Control Synthetic<br />

Zip codes: 10 12 43 10 12 43 10 12 43<br />

N 13,321 11,433 13,321 1,089 2,469 1,089 1,016 920 1,016<br />

FICO 621.75 622.47 623.07 630.11 624.67 629.42 614.68 620.77 618.96<br />

[60.95] [62.02] [60.05] [59.30] [60.46] [58.11] [56.37] [59.26] [54.85]<br />

FICO ≤ 620 (0/1) 0.49 0.49 0.47 0.42 0.47 0.42 0.55 0.49 0.50<br />

[0.50] [0.50] [0.50] [0.49] [0.50] [0.49] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50]<br />

Interest spread (%) 5.13 5.16 5.09 4.87 5.22 5.04 5.05 5.08 5.09<br />

[1.08] [1.11] [1.14] [0.84] [0.96] [1.09] [0.76] [0.85] [0.87]<br />

ARM (0/1) 0.86 0.86 0.87 0.74 0.77 0.80 0.64 0.61 0.63<br />

[0.35] [0.35] [0.33] [0.44] [0.42] [0.40] [0.48] [0.49] [0.48]<br />

No/low doc (0/1) 0.43 0.45 0.46 0.41 0.44 0.48 0.35 0.34 0.37<br />

[0.50] [0.50] [0.50] [0.49] [0.50] [0.50] [0.48] [0.48] [0.48]<br />

Category I (0/1) 0.89 0.90 0.91 0.82 0.84 0.88 0.72 0.70 0.74<br />

[0.31] [0.31] [0.29] [0.39] [0.37] [0.33] [0.45] [0.46] [0.44]<br />

Category II (0/1) 0.16 0.16 0.15 0.13 0.18 0.16 0.11 0.16 0.16<br />

[0.37] [0.37] [0.36] [0.34] [0.38] [0.36] [0.32] [0.37] [0.37]<br />

100% LTV (0/1) 0.16 0.15 0.15 0.14 0.15 0.14 0.06 0.05 0.05<br />

[0.37] [0.35] [0.36] [0.35] [0.36] [0.34] [0.24] [0.22] [0.21]<br />

LTV (%) 84.70 83.43 84.05 83.92 83.25 83.87 80.60 79.10 79.72<br />

[12.03] [12.83] [12.35] [12.09] [12.95] [11.81] [12.32] [13.50] [12.47]<br />

Excessive (0/1) 0.12 0.11 0.12 0.09 0.10 0.10 0.03 0.03 0.03<br />

[0.33] [0.32] [0.33] [0.28] [0.31] [0.30] [0.17] [0.18] [0.17]<br />

Defaulted within 18 months (0/1) 0.184 0.187 0.162 0.247 0.285 0.264 0.297 0.291 0.274<br />

[0.39] [0.39] [0.37] [0.43] [0.45] [0.44] [0.46] [0.45] [0.45]<br />

Defaulted within 36 months (0/1) 0.340 0.320 0.287 0.530 0.538 0.517 0.536 0.527 0.510<br />

[0.47] [0.47] [0.45] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50]<br />

Pre-treatment (1/2005-8/2006) Treatment Period (9/2006-1/2007) Post-treatment (2/2007-12/2007)<br />

HB 4050 Control Synthetic HB 4050 Control Synthetic HB 4050 Control Synthetic<br />

Zip codes: 10 12 43 10 12 43 10 12 43<br />

N 2,276 1,994 2,276 811 758 811 211 185 211<br />

FICO 642.78 639.90 645.64 641.77 635.57 643.57 649.71 647.41 651.28<br />

[61.76] [61.12] [60.56] [61.24] [57.44] [59.49] [63.68] [65.83] [63.32]<br />

FICO ≤ 620 (0/1) 0.37 0.38 0.35 0.34 0.38 0.33 0.34 0.36 0.32<br />

[0.48] [0.49] [0.48] [0.47] [0.49] [0.47] [0.47] [0.48] [0.47]<br />

Interest spread (%) 4.99 5.05 4.72 4.98 5.03 4.80 4.56 4.82 4.28<br />

[1.39] [1.32] [1.47] [1.22] [1.10] [1.21] [1.30] [1.21] [1.40]<br />

ARM (0/1) 0.68 0.70 0.72 0.65 0.67 0.70 0.48 0.54 0.55<br />

[0.47] [0.46] [0.45] [0.48] [0.47] [0.46] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50]<br />

No/low doc (0/1) 0.46 0.46 0.48 0.47 0.50 0.52 0.48 0.52 0.57<br />

[0.50] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50]<br />

Category I (0/1) 0.86 0.86 0.86 0.77 0.81 0.84 0.74 0.78 0.80<br />

[0.35] [0.35] [0.34] [0.42] [0.39] [0.37] [0.44] [0.42] [0.40]<br />

Category II (0/1) 0.39 0.40 0.35 0.19 0.20 0.18 0.36 0.29 0.26<br />

[0.49] [0.49] [0.48] [0.39] [0.40] [0.39] [0.48] [0.46] [0.44]<br />

100% LTV (0/1) 0.15 0.14 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.12 0.01 0.04 0.01<br />

[0.36] [0.35] [0.33] [0.34] [0.34] [0.32] [0.12] [0.20] [0.12]<br />

LTV (%) 82.94 81.87 82.02 82.95 82.61 82.35 77.59 77.05 77.23<br />

[13.72] [14.40] [13.47] [13.39] [13.91] [13.37] [13.24] [13.96] [12.09]<br />

Excessive (0/1) 0.09 0.08 0.09 0.09 0.10 0.09 0.00 0.04 0.03<br />

[0.29] [0.28] [0.28] [0.28] [0.30] [0.29] [0.07] [0.19] [0.18]<br />

Defaulted within 18 months (0/1) 0.156 0.135 0.114 0.207 0.240 0.203 0.147 0.254 0.190<br />

[0.36] [0.34] [0.32] [0.41] [0.43] [0.40] [0.35] [0.44] [0.39]<br />

Defaulted within 36 months (0/1) 0.300 0.276 0.239 0.471 0.471 0.428 0.379 0.465 0.389<br />

[0.46] [0.45] [0.43] [0.50] [0.50] [0.50] [0.49] [0.50] [0.49]<br />

42


Table 1. Summary Statistics (Cont.)<br />

Panel D: Mean and Standard Deviations of Lender-Level Characteristics for State-<br />

Licensed Lenders in the HB4050 Zip Codes in 6–8/2006<br />

N 49<br />

Lender exited during HB4050 (0/1) (>90% decline) 0.51<br />

[0.51]<br />

Share of category I loans 0.88<br />

[0.19]<br />

Share of category II loans 0.19<br />

[0.28]<br />

Share of excessive loans 0.15<br />

[0.22]<br />

log(Avg monthly # transactions) -0.16<br />

[2.07]<br />

Panel E: Means and Standard Deviations of Counseling Agency Data and Matched Loans<br />

HB 4050 loans Matched loans<br />

N 121 1,048<br />

Counselled 1.00 0.00<br />

0.00 0.00<br />

90 days delinquent (18 months) 0.13 0.13<br />

[0.34] [0.34]<br />

90 days delinquent (36 months) 0.41 0.28<br />

[0.49] [0.45]<br />

Foreclosure (18 months) 0.07 0.10<br />

[0.26] [0.30]<br />

Foreclosure (36 months) 0.20 0.21<br />

[0.40] [0.40]<br />

Red flag 0.38<br />

[0.49]<br />

Red flag (fraud) 0.12<br />

[0.32]<br />

Category I 0.84 0.82<br />

[0.36] [0.38]<br />

Category II 0.15 0.12<br />

[0.36] [0.33]<br />

LTV (%) 78.22 77.38<br />

[12.80] [13.68]<br />

Excessive 0.38 0.38<br />

[0.49] [0.49]<br />

log(Loan amount) 12.08 12.14<br />

[0.35] [0.38]<br />

43


Table 2. Effects of HB4050 on Market Activity: Application and Mortgage Volumes<br />

The table presents mortgage application and origination statistics for the pre-HB4050, HB4050, and post-<br />

HB4050 periods. The sample is stratified by lender type (all lenders, state-licensed lenders, and nonstate-licensed<br />

lenders) and by transaction type (all, purchases, and refinances). Note that the “Purchases”<br />

and “Refinances” categories do not necessarily add up to the “All” category because some mortgages<br />

have other purposes, e.g., home improvement. Panel A and Panel B present an analysis of mortgage<br />

applications using HMDA data. Panel C presents an analysis of mortgage originations using the matched<br />

LP-HMDA data. Panel D limits the sample to loans to borrowers with FICO scores lower than 620.<br />

Panel A: The Effect of HB4050 on the Number of Mortgage Applications (HMDA Sample)<br />

# Applications per Month for State-Licensed Lenders<br />

All HB4050 zip codes<br />

All Control zip codes<br />

All Purchases Refinances All Purchases Refinances<br />

1/2005-8/2006 4,813 2,201 2,507 4,218 1,949 2,175<br />

9/2006-1/2007 (HB4050 period) 2,371 1,086 1,238 3,642 1,631 1,937<br />

2/2007-12/2007 2,136 619 1,453 1,882 593 1,240<br />

Diff (9/06-1/07 vs. 1/05-8/06) -50.7% -50.7% -50.6% -13.7% -16.3% -11.0%<br />

Diff-in-diff -37.1% -34.3% -39.7%<br />

# Applications per Month for Non-State-Licensed Lenders<br />

All HB4050 zip codes<br />

All Control zip codes<br />

All Purchases Refinances All Purchases Refinances<br />

1/2005-8/2006 1,676 561 984 1,362 479 780<br />

9/2006-1/2007 (HB4050 period) 1,808 644 1,000 1,585 615 851<br />

2/2007-12/2007 1,885 623 1,091 1,585 561 884<br />

Diff (9/06-1/07 vs. 1/05-8/06) 7.9% 14.7% 1.6% 16.4% 28.6% 9.1%<br />

Diff-in-diff -8.5% -13.9% -7.5%<br />

Diff-in-diff-in-diff -28.6% -20.5% -32.2%<br />

44


Table 2. Effects of HB4050 on Market Activity: Application and Mortgage Volumes (Cont.)<br />

Panel B: The Effect of HB4050 on the Number of Originated Mortgages (HMDA Sample)<br />

# Mortgages per Month for State-Licensed Lenders<br />

All HB4050 zip codes<br />

All Control zip codes<br />

All Purchases Refinances All Purchases Refinances<br />

1/2005-8/2006 1,803 912 854 1,507 760 716<br />

9/2006-1/2007 (HB4050 period) 703 294 394 1,245 529 693<br />

2/2007-12/2007 582 154 406 508 153 339<br />

Diff (9/06-1/07 vs. 1/05-8/06) -61.0% -67.7% -53.9% -17.4% -30.4% -3.2%<br />

Diff-in-diff -43.6% -37.3% -50.7%<br />

# Mortgages per Month for Non-State-Licensed Lenders<br />

All HB4050 zip codes<br />

All Control zip codes<br />

All Purchases Refinances All Purchases Refinances<br />

1/2005-8/2006 711 252 409 552 199 315<br />

9/2006-1/2007 (HB4050 period) 772 261 440 627 222 355<br />

2/2007-12/2007 722 240 418 586 209 326<br />

Diff (9/06-1/07 vs. 1/05-8/06) 8.5% 3.4% 7.5% 13.6% 11.9% 12.7%<br />

Diff-in-diff -5.0% -8.5% -5.1%<br />

Diff-in-diff-in-diff -38.6% -28.8% -45.5%<br />

Panel C: The Effect of HB4050 on the Number of Originated Mortgages for Borrowers<br />

with FICO ≤ 620 (LP-HMDA Sample)<br />

# Mortgages per Month for State-Licensed Lenders<br />

All HB4050 zip codes<br />

All Control zip codes<br />

All Purchases Refinances All Purchases Refinances<br />

1/2005-8/2006 666 278 388 572 237 335<br />

9/2006-1/2007 (HB4050 period) 218 71 147 494 163 331<br />

2/2007-12/2007 92 16 76 84 16 68<br />

Diff (9/06-1/07 vs. 1/05-8/06) -67.3% -74.5% -62.2% -13.6% -31.2% -1.2%<br />

Diff-in-diff -53.7% -43.3% -61.0%<br />

# Mortgages per Month for Non-State-Licensed Lenders<br />

All HB4050 zip codes<br />

All Control zip codes<br />

All Purchases Refinances All Purchases Refinances<br />

1/2005-8/2006 114 45 68 100 36 64<br />

9/2006-1/2007 (HB4050 period) 162 57 105 152 51 100<br />

2/2007-12/2007 19 3 16 17 4 13<br />

Diff (9/06-1/07 vs. 1/05-8/06) 42.5% 25.1% 54.1% 52.1% 42.2% 57.7%<br />

Diff-in-diff -9.5% -17.1% -3.6%<br />

Diff-in-diff-in-diff -44.2% -26.2% -57.4%<br />

45


Table 3. Effects of HB4050 on Mortgage Characteristics<br />

The table presents regressions of borrower and mortgage characteristics on the HB4050 indicator. The<br />

sample used in Panel A includes all lenders. The sample used in Panel B includes only lenders who stayed<br />

in the market during the treatment period in the HB4050 zip codes. HB4050 is an indicator of whether the<br />

loan was originated in the treated HB4050 zip codes during the treatment period. FICO is the FICO credit<br />

score of the borrower. Interest spread measures the interest spread over the same-maturity treasury rate<br />

(for fixed rate mortgages) or the quoted interest spread (for adjustable rate mortgages). ARM is an<br />

indicator of whether a mortgage is an adjustable rate mortgage. No/low doc is an indicator of whether the<br />

loan required no or low documentation. Category I is an indicator of interest-only loans, loans with<br />

interest rate adjustments within three years, or loans underwritten on the basis of stated income (no/lowdoc<br />

loans). Category II includes loans with negative amortization or prepayment penalties. 100% LTV is<br />

an indicator of whether the loan has a 100% loan-to-value ratio. Excessive mortgages are defined by<br />

HB4050 as mortgages that are ARM, low documentation, interest-only, and ≥95% LTV. Standard errors,<br />

presented in parentheses, are clustered at the zip code level. *, **, and *** denote statistical significance<br />

at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.<br />

Panel A: All Lenders<br />

Interest No/low Category I Category II 100% LTV Excessive<br />

Dependent variable: FICO spread (%) ARM (0/1) doc (0/1) (0/1) (0/1) (0/1) (0/1)<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)<br />

HB4050 Zip Code 7.842*** -0.429*** -0.052** 0.007 -0.026 -0.039** -0.025 -0.022**<br />

× State licensed lender (1.933) (0.036) (0.020) (0.017) (0.019) (0.014) (0.018) (0.011)<br />

Month × State licensed FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Zip × State licensed FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Observations 36,483 29,367 36,483 36,483 36,483 36,483 36,483 36,483<br />

Adj. R 2 0.035 0.042 0.057 0.067 0.044 0.041 0.016 0.025<br />

Panel B: Lenders Who Stayed in HB4050 Zip Codes during the Treatment Period<br />

Interest No/low Category I Category II 100% LTV Excessive<br />

Dependent variable: FICO spread (%) ARM (0/1) doc (0/1) (0/1) (0/1) (0/1) (0/1)<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)<br />

HB4050 Zip Code 7.770*** -0.295*** -0.022 0.019 -0.011 -0.043** -0.035* -0.021<br />

× State licensed lender (1.888) (0.037) (0.023) (0.021) (0.021) (0.016) (0.018) (0.013)<br />

Month × State licensed FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Zip × State licensed FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Observations 22,311 17,385 22,311 22,311 22,311 22,311 22,311 22,311<br />

Adj. R 2 0.042 0.067 0.071 0.072 0.050 0.082 0.022 0.023<br />

46


Table 4. Exit of Lenders Due to HB4050<br />

The table presents analysis of lender exit during the HB4050 pilot. Panel A presents statistics about the<br />

number of lenders in the treatment and control areas during different time periods. Panel B shows<br />

summary statistics of lenders by whether they stayed or exited the HB4050 zip codes during the antipredatory<br />

pilot. The statistics presented are based on 55 lenders identified in the matched sample HMDA-<br />

LP and are based on pre-announcement statistics from January to December 2005.<br />

Panel A: Number of Lenders Operating in the Treatment and Controls Areas<br />

# State-licensed lenders # Non-state-licensed lenders<br />

HB4050 Control Synthetic HB4050 Control Synthetic<br />

Pre HB4050 (1/2005 - 8/2006) 89 79 87 33 33 35<br />

HB4050 (9/2006 - 1/2007) 46 63 61 23 27 24<br />

Post HB4050 (2/2007 - 12/2007) 28 29 30 15 14 18<br />

Diff (9/06-1/07 vs. 1/05-8/06) -48.3% -20.3% -29.9% -30.3% -18.2% -31.4%<br />

Diff-in-Diff (Control) -18.4% 1.1%<br />

Diff-in-Diff (Synthetic) -28.1% -12.1%<br />

Diff-in-Diff-in-Diff (Control) -19.6%<br />

Diff-in-Diff-in-Diff (Synthetic) -15.9%<br />

Panel B: Characteristics of Lenders Who Exited the HB4050 Zip Codes (Based on 2005<br />

Originations)<br />

State-licensed lenders Non-state-licensed lenders<br />

Statistics in Jan-Dec/2005 Stayed Exited Stayed Exited<br />

# Mortgages (per month) 17.7 11.6 4.8 0.7<br />

Avg FICO 645.8 639.6 675.5 710.5<br />

Avg interest spread (%) 4.84 4.73 4.10 3.30<br />

% Arm (0/1) 74.0% 83.8% 59.2% 50.0%<br />

% Low doc 45.0% 52.6% 61.3% 100.0%<br />

% Category I 86.6% 93.0% 81.3% 100.0%<br />

% Category II 26.8% 29.0% 35.7% 0.0%<br />

% Default within 18 months 10.4% 11.6% 9.2% 12.5%<br />

% 100% LTV 22.7% 14.6% 8.9% 0.0%<br />

% Excessive 11.2% 14.0% 6.6% 0.0%<br />

# Lenders 21 22 11 1<br />

47


Table 5. The Effect of HB4050 on Borrower Default<br />

The table presents regressions of borrower defaults. Panels A and B present baseline regressions. Panels A and C<br />

use the treatment sample and a control sample based on zip codes with similar demographics. Panels B and D use<br />

the treatment sample and a control sample based on one-to-one loan matching (the synthetic control sample). Panel<br />

E uses both control samples. In each panel, there are six regression specifications. In all regressions, we regress the<br />

default indicator on the treatment dummy with the following: zip code interacted with calendar month, zip code<br />

interacted with a state-licensed lender indicator, and calendar month interacted with a state-licensed lender indicator.<br />

These three sets of fixed effects control for variations in all three dimensions that define the treatment: treatment zip<br />

code, treatment month, and treatment lender group. In Column (1) in each panel, we include no other controls. In<br />

Column (2), we include controls for FICO score and logged loan amount. In Column (3), we include a no/low<br />

documentation indicator, indicators of whether the loan is Category I or Category II, and an LTV variable. Columns<br />

(4) to (6) repeat the specifications of Columns (1) to (3) but add lender fixed effects. The dependent variable is an<br />

indicator of borrower default (within 18 or 36 months). Default is defined as a 90-day delinquency. HB4050 is an<br />

indicator of whether the loan was originated in the treated HB4050 zip codes during the treatment period. FICO/100<br />

is the FICO credit score of the borrower (divided by 100). No/low doc is an indicator of whether the loan required no<br />

or low documentation. Category I is an indicator for interest-only loans, loans with interest rate adjustments within<br />

three years, or loans underwritten on the basis of stated income (no/low-doc loans). Category II includes loans with<br />

negative amortization or prepayment penalties. The tables also show statistics about the default rate in the control<br />

group. Standard errors, presented in parentheses, are clustered at the zip code level. *, **, and *** denote statistical<br />

significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.<br />

Panel A: All LP-HMDA Loans; HB4050 Loans and Control Sample<br />

Sample:<br />

Dependent variable:<br />

Default rate for the control group during pilot:<br />

All mortgages, 2005-2007; Control is based on 12 zip codes<br />

Default within 18 months (0/1)<br />

0.274<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

HB4050 Zip × Month × Lender 0.010 0.009 0.008 0.001 0.000 0.002<br />

(0.025) (0.024) (0.023) (0.028) (0.027) (0.026)<br />

FICO/100 -0.045*** -0.071*** -0.044*** -0.068***<br />

(0.006) (0.005) (0.006) (0.005)<br />

log(Loan amount) 0.167*** 0.098*** 0.152*** 0.094***<br />

(0.015) (0.016) (0.014) (0.015)<br />

No/low doc 0.048*** 0.047***<br />

(0.007) (0.007)<br />

Category I 0.059*** 0.060***<br />

(0.007) (0.007)<br />

Category II -0.016** -0.021**<br />

(0.005) (0.007)<br />

LTV 0.003*** 0.003***<br />

(0.000) (0.000)<br />

Zip code FE x Month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Zip code FE x State-licensed FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Month FE x State-licensed FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Lender FE No No No Yes Yes Yes<br />

Observations 36,483 36,483 36,483 36,483 36,483 36,483<br />

Adj. R 2 0.043 0.064 0.082 0.059 0.077 0.092<br />

48


Table 5. The Effect of HB4050 on Borrower Default (Cont.)<br />

Panel B: All LP-HMDA Loans; HB4050 Loans and Loan-Matched Sample<br />

Sample:<br />

Dependent variable:<br />

Default rate for the control group during pilot:<br />

All mortgages, 2005-2007; Control is based on loan matching<br />

Default within 18 months (0/1)<br />

0.238<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

HB4050 Zip × Month × Lender -0.009 -0.013 -0.011 -0.026 -0.029 -0.022<br />

(0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.030) (0.030) (0.029)<br />

FICO/100 -0.050*** -0.077*** -0.049*** -0.073***<br />

(0.006) (0.005) (0.006) (0.005)<br />

log(Loan amount) 0.153*** 0.087*** 0.139*** 0.085***<br />

(0.016) (0.016) (0.015) (0.015)<br />

No/low doc 0.047*** 0.046***<br />

(0.006) (0.006)<br />

Category I 0.058*** 0.060***<br />

(0.006) (0.007)<br />

Category II -0.011* -0.015*<br />

(0.005) (0.006)<br />

LTV 0.003*** 0.003***<br />

(0.000) (0.000)<br />

Zip code FE x Month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Zip code FE x State-licensed FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Month FE x State-licensed FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Lender FE No No No Yes Yes Yes<br />

Observations 37,448 37,448 37,448 37,448 37,448 37,448<br />

Adj. R 2 0.039 0.058 0.075 0.054 0.070 0.084<br />

49


Table 5. The Effect of HB4050 on Borrower Default (Cont.)<br />

Panel C: Default Regression with Sample Limited to Low FICO Score; Control Zip Codes<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) N Default rate for control<br />

FICO≤ 620 loans by state-licensed & non-state-licensed lenders<br />

Treatment -0.008 -0.006 -0.012 -0.038 -0.034 -0.033 16,967 0.257<br />

(0.043) (0.043) (0.041) (0.041) (0.040) (0.039)<br />

Adj. R 2 0.028 0.043 0.058 0.039 0.051 0.065<br />

All loans by state-licensed lenders<br />

Treatment -0.034 -0.035 -0.028 -0.036 -0.038 -0.029 30,248 0.285<br />

(0.020) (0.021) (0.019) (0.023) (0.023) (0.022)<br />

Adj. R 2 0.038 0.058 0.076 0.049 0.066 0.082<br />

All FICO≤ 620 loans by state-licensed lenders<br />

Treatment -0.045 -0.048* -0.039 -0.048 -0.051* -0.041 14,668 0.264<br />

(0.026) (0.026) (0.025) (0.028) (0.028) (0.027)<br />

Adj. R 2 0.027 0.040 0.056 0.034 0.045 0.060<br />

All FICO≤ 620 loans by state-licensed lenders that did not exit<br />

Treatment -0.027 -0.031 -0.020 -0.033 -0.036 -0.027 8,583 0.204<br />

(0.028) (0.027) (0.026) (0.028) (0.027) (0.026)<br />

Adj. R 2 (0.026) 0.043 0.061 0.031 0.047 0.064<br />

Panel D: Default Regression with Sample Limited to Low FICO Score; Synthetic Control<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) N Default rate for control<br />

FICO≤ 620 loans by state-licensed & non-state-licensed lenders<br />

Treatment -0.040 -0.039 -0.042 -0.069 -0.065 -0.064 17,080 0.248<br />

(0.046) (0.047) (0.045) (0.047) (0.047) (0.045)<br />

Adj. R 2 0.028 0.041 0.055 0.039 0.049 0.062<br />

All loans by state-licensed lenders<br />

Treatment -0.038 -0.044* -0.034 -0.043 -0.049* -0.037 30,852 0.264<br />

(0.023) (0.024) (0.023) (0.025) (0.025) (0.025)<br />

Adj. R 2 0.040 0.057 0.074 0.050 0.065 0.080<br />

All FICO≤ 620 loans by state-licensed lenders<br />

Treatment -0.064* -0.071** -0.059* -0.070** -0.075** -0.064* 14,776 0.272<br />

(0.032) (0.032) (0.031) (0.034) (0.034) (0.033)<br />

Adj. R 2 0.028 0.039 0.055 0.036 0.045 0.060<br />

All FICO≤ 620 loans by state-licensed lenders that did not exit<br />

Treatment -0.036 -0.042 -0.026 -0.042 -0.047 -0.033 8,529 0.193<br />

(0.037) (0.036) (0.035) (0.035) (0.034) (0.034)<br />

Adj. R 2 0.054 0.070 0.093 0.067 0.079 0.099<br />

50


Table 5. The Effect of HB4050 on Borrower Default (Cont.)<br />

Panel E: 36-Month Default Regressions<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) N Default rate for control<br />

Control is based on 12 zip codes; All loans by state-licensed & non-state-licensed lenders<br />

Treatment -0.006 -0.008 -0.009 -0.017 -0.019 -0.017 36,483 0.522<br />

(0.035) (0.033) (0.032) (0.037) (0.035) (0.034)<br />

Adj. R 2 0.076 0.106 0.133 0.094 0.118 0.141<br />

Control is based on 12 zip codes; All FICO≤ 620 loans by state-licensed lenders<br />

Treatment -0.045 -0.050 -0.036 -0.050 -0.053 -0.039 14,668 0.515<br />

(0.031) (0.032) (0.030) (0.032) (0.032) (0.031)<br />

Adj. R 2 0.057 0.077 0.102 0.070 0.086 0.108<br />

Control is based on loan matching; All loans by state-licensed & Non-state-licensed lenders<br />

Treatment -0.026 -0.031 -0.028 -0.036 -0.039 -0.031 37,448 0.479<br />

(0.040) (0.039) (0.038) (0.041) (0.040) (0.039)<br />

Adj. R 2 0.076 0.099 0.125 0.092 0.111 0.133<br />

Control is based on loan matching; All FICO≤ 620 loans by state-licensed lenders<br />

Treatment -0.054 -0.063* -0.045 -0.057 -0.065* -0.048 14,776 0.500<br />

(0.037) (0.037) (0.035) (0.036) (0.036) (0.034)<br />

Adj. R 2 0.054 0.070 0.093 0.067 0.079 0.099<br />

51


Table 6. Measuring the Default Rate of <strong>Predatory</strong> Loans Using the HB4050 Data Set<br />

The table presents analysis of a sample of counseled loans (121 loans) and a control sample of loans<br />

matched from other Chicago zip codes (every counseled loan is matched with up to ten similar loans from<br />

Chicago). Panel A presents the sample of 121 counseled loans. Panel B presents the sample of 121<br />

together with the 1,048 matched loans. The dependent variable is an indicator of borrower default within<br />

18 months. Default is defined as a 90-day delinquency. Red flag is an indicator of whether the counseled<br />

loan was identified as unaffordable or fraudulent by the HUD-certified counselors. Red flag (fraud) is an<br />

indicator of whether the counseled loan was identified as having fraud indicia. No/low doc is an indicator<br />

of whether the loan required no or low documentation. Category I is an indicator for interest-only loans,<br />

loans with interest rate adjustments within three years, or loans underwritten on the basis of stated income<br />

(no/low-doc loans). Category II includes loans with negative amortization or prepayment penalties.<br />

Excessive mortgages are mortgages that are ARM, no/low documentation, interest-only, or ≥95% LTV.<br />

Standard errors, presented in parentheses, are clustered at the zip code level. *, **, and *** denote<br />

statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.<br />

Panel A: <strong>Predatory</strong> Loans in the Counseled Sample<br />

Dependent variable: Defaulted within 18 months (0/1)<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

Red flag 0.065 0.036<br />

(0.068) (0.072)<br />

Red flag (fraud) 0.123 0.111<br />

(0.106) (0.111)<br />

No/low doc -0.081 -0.085<br />

(0.079) (0.079)<br />

Category I 0.210* 0.224**<br />

(0.112) (0.111)<br />

Category II 0.024 0.036<br />

(0.103) (0.102)<br />

LTV 0.001 0.002<br />

(0.003) (0.003)<br />

Excessive 0.100 0.066<br />

(0.207) (0.210)<br />

log(Loan amount) 0.161 0.144<br />

(0.124) (0.124)<br />

Month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Observations 121 115 121 115<br />

Adj. R 2 -0.046 -0.018 -0.042 -0.010<br />

52


Table 6. Measuring the Default Rate of <strong>Predatory</strong> Loans Using the HB4050 Data Set<br />

(Cont.)<br />

Panel B: Comparing the Counseled Sample to a Comparable Sample in the Control Zip<br />

Codes (18-Month Default Rate)<br />

Dependent variable: Defaulted within 18 months (0/1)<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

Red flag 0.061* 0.063*<br />

(0.036) (0.037)<br />

Counseled × Red flag -0.011<br />

(0.065)<br />

Red flag (fraud) 0.061 0.055<br />

(0.075) (0.075)<br />

Counseled × Red flag (fraud) 0.051<br />

(0.102)<br />

Counseled -0.000 0.004 -0.001 -0.007<br />

(0.032) (0.041) (0.032) (0.034)<br />

Month FE Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Observations 1,159 1,159 1,159 1,159<br />

Adj. R 2 0.012 0.011 0.008 0.007<br />

53


Figure 1. HB4050 Treatment and Control Zip Codes<br />

This figure presents a map of the HB4050 treatment area (the shaded area) and the control zip codes (the<br />

striped area). As described in Section 3.3, the 12–zip code control area is constructed to resemble the<br />

treatment area in terms of pretreatment socioeconomic characteristics and housing market conditions. The<br />

socioeconomic variables used for selection include 2005 Internal Revenue Service (IRS) zip code–level<br />

income statistics, the 2000 Census shares of minority population and of those living below the poverty<br />

level, and the unemployment rate. Housing market metrics include default rates on mortgages originated<br />

in 2005 as well as zip code–level means of FICO scores, LTV and DTI ratios, and housing values. All of<br />

the control zip codes lie within the City of Chicago limits. The 12–zip code control area has about as<br />

many residents as the treatment area.<br />

54


Figure 2. HMDA Loan Application Filings<br />

This figure presents a time series of loan application filings. Figure 2a depicts filings in both the treatment<br />

and control areas, separating lenders subject to HB4050 and those exempt from it. Figure 2b focuses only<br />

on the treatment areas, differentiating between lenders that remained active during the mandate period<br />

and those that exited HB4050 zip codes. The solid vertical lines denote the time during which HB4050<br />

was in force.<br />

Figure 2a. Number of Mortgage Applications in HB4050 Zip Codes and in Control Zip<br />

Codes, per State-Licensed and Non-State-Licensed Lenders<br />

6,000<br />

State-Licensed Lenders (subject to HB4050)<br />

6,000<br />

Non-State-Licensed Lenders (Exempt from HB4050)<br />

5,000<br />

5,000<br />

Number of Applications<br />

4,000<br />

3,000<br />

2,000<br />

1,000<br />

HB4050 zip codes<br />

Control zip codes<br />

Number of Applications<br />

4,000<br />

3,000<br />

2,000<br />

1,000<br />

HB4050 zip codes<br />

Control zip codes<br />

0<br />

0<br />

Jan-05<br />

Mar-05<br />

May-05<br />

Jul-05<br />

Sep-05<br />

Nov-05<br />

Jan-06<br />

Mar-06<br />

May-06<br />

Jul-06<br />

Sep-06<br />

Nov-06<br />

Jan-07<br />

Mar-07<br />

May-07<br />

Jul-07<br />

Sep-07<br />

Nov-07<br />

Jan-05<br />

Mar-05<br />

May-05<br />

Jul-05<br />

Sep-05<br />

Nov-05<br />

Jan-06<br />

Mar-06<br />

May-06<br />

Jul-06<br />

Sep-06<br />

Nov-06<br />

Jan-07<br />

Mar-07<br />

May-07<br />

Jul-07<br />

Sep-07<br />

Nov-07<br />

Figure 2b. Number of Mortgage Originations in HB4050 Zip Codes and in Control Zip<br />

Codes, per State-Licensed and Non-State-Licensed Lenders<br />

2,500<br />

State-Licensed Lenders (subject to HB4050)<br />

2,500<br />

Non-State-Licensed Lenders (Exempt from HB4050)<br />

2,000<br />

2,000<br />

Number of Originations<br />

1,500<br />

1,000<br />

500<br />

HB4050 zip codes<br />

Control zip codes<br />

Number of Originations<br />

1,500<br />

1,000<br />

500<br />

HB4050 zip codes<br />

0<br />

0<br />

Jan-05<br />

Mar-05<br />

May-05<br />

Jul-05<br />

Sep-05<br />

Nov-05<br />

Jan-06<br />

Mar-06<br />

May-06<br />

Jul-06<br />

Sep-06<br />

Nov-06<br />

Jan-07<br />

Mar-07<br />

May-07<br />

Jul-07<br />

Sep-07<br />

Nov-07<br />

Jan-05<br />

Mar-05<br />

May-05<br />

Jul-05<br />

Sep-05<br />

Nov-05<br />

Jan-06<br />

Mar-06<br />

May-06<br />

Jul-06<br />

Sep-06<br />

Nov-06<br />

Jan-07<br />

Mar-07<br />

May-07<br />

Jul-07<br />

Sep-07<br />

Nov-07<br />

Control zip codes<br />

55


Page 154 of 181


Attachment C<br />

Subprime and <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong><br />

In Rural America<br />

Page 155 of 181


CARSEY<br />

POLICY BRIEF NO. 4<br />

C A R S E Y I N S T I T U T E 1<br />

FALL 2006<br />

I N S T I T U T E<br />

Subprime and <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> in Rural America:<br />

Mortgage lending practices that can trap low-income rural people<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> lending, which encompasses a range of<br />

financial practices that are often targeted at lowincome<br />

individuals and threaten their income and<br />

assets, is becoming increasingly prevalent in rural<br />

communities. While predatory lending practices can include<br />

check-cashing outlets for payday loans, car title loans, refund<br />

anticipation loans and rent-a-center loans, among others, 1<br />

this report focuses on predatory practices in the housing<br />

market. A home is usually a person’s largest investment,<br />

making home mortgages a prime target for predatory lending.<br />

Using targeted marketing and promises of “easy credit”<br />

and “quick cash,” predatory lenders can trap borrowers in a<br />

cycle of high interest payments, abusive fees and terms that<br />

can lead to home foreclosures, and ultimately devastate borrowers’<br />

financial futures.<br />

Individuals and communities that have few lending<br />

options are vulnerable to predatory products. 2 The use of<br />

these products appears to be growing in rural areas, where<br />

there are fewer commercial financial banking firms serving<br />

rural borrowers than in urban counties. 3 Lacking access<br />

to financial alternatives, rural residents are susceptible to a<br />

range of predatory financial institutions and products that<br />

charge excessive fees and diminish their ability to save and<br />

build wealth.<br />

This brief examines predatory mortgage loans, which have<br />

emerged in the expanding subprime mortgage market, looking<br />

at who is most at risk of being abused by such lending<br />

practices and where these practices occur. One key finding<br />

is that rural minorities are more likely than whites to take<br />

out High APR Loans or “HALs.” The report also details the<br />

widespread use of HALs to purchase manufactured housing,<br />

a key component of the rural housing market. A Maine case<br />

study illustrates the persistence of predatory lending in rural<br />

communities. The report concludes with recommendations<br />

to address predatory lending practices at the federal and<br />

state levels.<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> Mortgage <strong>Lending</strong> Hurts<br />

Families<br />

Children have a better chance for success when they are<br />

raised in families who own their own home and have stable<br />

financial assets. When parents or caregivers have little savings<br />

to fall back on, they may seek assistance from predatory<br />

lenders, as the story below illustrates.<br />

Ms. Leah Pyy grew up in Falmouth, Maine in a clam shop<br />

with no running water, and she always dreamed of owning<br />

a home. In 1995, she and her husband bought a home for<br />

themselves and their grandson, who had been living with<br />

them since 1993.<br />

“The house means the world to me, especially since it’s a<br />

safe place for my grandchild to live and play,” Ms. Pyy said.<br />

She had been in a serious car accident years before that<br />

left her disabled, and it was not easy for the family to make<br />

ends meet. After buying the house, the Pyys went into debt<br />

and fell behind on their house payments.<br />

“I heard that you could get out of debt by using your<br />

home equity to pay credit card bills,” Ms. Pyy said, who<br />

soon found herself ensnared in a predatory mortgage loan.<br />

“There were a lot of loan papers, a lot of fine print that didn’t<br />

mean anything to me. We were desperate, and the bank<br />

seemed to be offering us a way out.”<br />

They obtained a second mortgage for $31,500 at an interest<br />

rate of 13.75 percent that cost $4,787 in closing costs.<br />

As a result of this expensive mortgage loan, the Pyys fell<br />

deeper and deeper in debt.<br />

Although she now understands how to avoid predatory<br />

lending traps, Ms. Pyy continues to receive calls every week<br />

from mortgage companies that want to lend her more<br />

money.<br />

“These days, I know better – but I’m sure they’re reaching<br />

a lot of others who are desperate, as I was,” Ms. Pyy added.<br />

Adapted from “Statement of Ms. Leah Pyy, Victim of <strong>Predatory</strong><br />

Mortgage <strong>Lending</strong>,” presented at Coastal Enterprises, Inc.<br />

press conference, February 13, 2006.


2 C A R S E Y I N S T I T U T E<br />

The Subprime Mortgage Market and<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong><br />

Identifying a <strong>Predatory</strong> Mortgage Loan<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> mortgage lending includes a range of abusive<br />

terms and activities, including the following:<br />

• Excessive points and fees—Points and fees in excess<br />

of five percent of the total loan amount are considered<br />

excessive.<br />

• Prepayment penalties—Penalty fees imposed on<br />

borrowers who repay all or the majority of a loan before<br />

a set time period.<br />

• Loan flipping—Refinancing a mortgage loan without<br />

conveying a net benefit to the borrower, usually in order<br />

to extract additional fees and charges.<br />

• Steering—A borrower is “steered” to take out a higher<br />

cost loan than they could have qualified for.<br />

• Financed credit insurance—Financing mortgage<br />

insurance through a lump-sum payment folded into the<br />

mortgage loan.<br />

Adapted from:<br />

Dickstein, Carla et al., 2006. <strong>Predatory</strong> Mortgages in Maine:<br />

Recent Trends and the Persistence of Abusive <strong>Lending</strong><br />

Practices in the Subprime Mortgage Market. Coastal<br />

Enterprises, Inc., and Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>.<br />

Subprime mortgages carry higher costs than prime loans, ostensibly<br />

to compensate lenders for the added risks imposed<br />

by borrowers who may be at greater risk to fail to repay their<br />

loans. In recent years, the subprime mortgage market has increased<br />

significantly. In 1996, subprime lenders reported $90<br />

billion in lending. By 2004, the subprime mortgage market<br />

had grown to $401 billion. 4<br />

Within the subprime market, loans with interest rates at<br />

least three percentage points higher than that of U.S. Treasury<br />

securities of comparable maturity are considered High<br />

APR Loans (HALs). 5 Examining the prevalence of HALs has<br />

been difficult, given the lack of consistent data. However, the<br />

most recent Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) 6 data<br />

provide some important insights into this market.<br />

Even more costly are what the federal Home Ownership<br />

Equal Protection Act (HOEPA) defines as “high-cost loans.”<br />

These loans charge points and fees that are 8 percent or more<br />

of the mortgage amount (10 percent for second mortgages)<br />

and interest rates of 8 percent above the U.S. Treasury yield.<br />

A “high-cost” loan triggers certain consumer protections<br />

under federal law and under some state laws, such as those<br />

discussed in the Maine case study included in this brief.<br />

Subprime lenders avoid making high-cost loans so the actual<br />

number of loans of this type is negligible.<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> mortgage loans have been defined as those<br />

loans that (1) charge more in interest and fees than needed<br />

to cover the associated risk; (2) contain abusive terms and<br />

conditions (see box); and/or (3) do not take into account the<br />

borrower’s ability to repay. They often target women, minorities,<br />

and communities of color. 7 <strong>Predatory</strong> loans can add a<br />

great deal to the cost of mortgages, costs most low-income<br />

borrowers cannot afford. It is important to recognize, however,<br />

that although predatory loans are concentrated in the<br />

subprime market, not all subprime loans or even HALs are<br />

predatory. As subprime lending activity has increased, concern<br />

over wealth-stripping predatory lending has increased<br />

as well.<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> loans often contain a consumer-unfriendly prepayment<br />

penalty, which is assessed if a borrower pays off the<br />

loan before a specified time has elapsed. Prepayment penalties<br />

can trap consumers in subprime loans—even if they<br />

qualify for a lower-cost loan—because they cannot afford the<br />

prepayment penalty. These penalties drain equity from the<br />

borrowers when they refinance or sell their homes and create<br />

an incentive for borrowers to continue paying on loans with<br />

higher costs than they might otherwise qualify for.<br />

A B O U T T H E D A T A<br />

Since 1975, the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) has required that all depository financial institutions that meet a specific asset<br />

level and are headquartered in a metropolitan area are required to report information on mortgage applications. This geographically<br />

based dataset provides demographic information on the applicant, the loan disposition, and other characteristics that can be used to<br />

track lending rates and trends.<br />

This information brief presents Housing Assistance Council (HAC) tabulations of 2004 Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) data.<br />

For the first time in 2004, HMDA data include interest rate information for approved mortgage loans, providing important insight into<br />

the subprime lending market.<br />

While HMDA data are a critical resource to understanding lending trends, the limitations of these data in rural America must be acknowledged.<br />

Only those depository institutions with assets of $33 million (adjusted to $35 million in 2005) that were headquartered in<br />

a metropolitan area were required to report HMDA data in 2004. Consequently, an untold number of rural lending data are unavailable,<br />

as many small, rural financial institutions were not required to report HMDA data. Despite these limitations, HMDA provides the best<br />

available information on rural lending and high cost mortgage loans.


C A R S E Y I N S T I T U T E 3<br />

Some researchers who have analyzed predatory lending<br />

have characterized it as “redlining in reverse.” 8 The same<br />

poor and minority communities that were often denied access<br />

to credit are now being flooded with loan products that<br />

often strip equity and diminish wealth. Research has shown<br />

that African American and Hispanic borrowers are more<br />

likely to receive HALs than similarly qualified white borrowers,<br />

regardless of income. 9 Steering borrowers to loans with<br />

higher fees and interest rates than they could qualify for is a<br />

major component of predatory lending. It has been estimated<br />

that as many as half of all subprime loan borrowers could<br />

in fact qualify for conventional rate mortgages. 10<br />

Rural High APR <strong>Lending</strong><br />

As shown in the HMDA data, among the 555,941 rural<br />

mortgage loan originations reported in the 2004 HMDA<br />

data, 17.4 percent, or nearly 97,000, were classified as HALs.<br />

This was slightly higher than the national and metro rates.<br />

Further analysis of these data also shows that HALs are<br />

concentrated in rural areas with chronic poverty, and, often,<br />

a high proportion of minorities. Figure 1 illustrates the<br />

location of HALs in rural America as identified in the 2004<br />

HMDA data.<br />

As shown in Figure 1, HALs can be found in rural<br />

counties throughout the U.S., but there are some regional<br />

differences. Throughout the northeast and the far west, most<br />

rural counties have high APR lending rates of less than 20<br />

percent. Rates of high APR lending increase considerably in<br />

the central and southern regions of the country, particularly<br />

in rural areas that have historically high rates of poverty and<br />

racial and ethnic minorities. In almost 500 rural counties,<br />

nearly all of them in central and southern regions, one-third<br />

or more of the total mortgage originations were for HALs.<br />

These higher rates of high APR loans occur overwhelmingly<br />

in Persistent Poverty Counties. Figure 2 shows the location<br />

of Persistent Poverty Counties—those counties that have<br />

had poverty rates of 20 percent or more for the last three<br />

decades.<br />

Connected to these issues of location are issues of race<br />

and ethnicity. As the map shows, concentrations of HALs<br />

can be found across the Mississippi Delta region, in counties<br />

with Native American reservations and poor Hispanic-<br />

American communities, and in some Appalachian communities.<br />

Half of the counties with significant rates of higher<br />

cost loans –30 percent or more – are counties with minority<br />

populations of 33 percent or more.<br />

Rural America tends to be more racially and ethnically<br />

homogenous than the rest of the nation. Less than one-fifth<br />

of rural residents are minorities and 11 percent of all rural<br />

homeowners are minorities. As in urban areas, minorities<br />

in rural America receive a disproportionate share of HALs.<br />

Although, rural minorities account for less than 9 percent<br />

Table 1. 2004 High APR Mortgage Loan Originations,<br />

HMDA<br />

Total Loans<br />

High APR Mortgages<br />

# %<br />

Urban 5,243,959 810,934 15.5%<br />

Rural 555,941 96,897 17.4%<br />

National 5,799,900 907,831 15.6%<br />

Source: HAC tabulations of 2004 HMDA data.<br />

Figure 1: Map of High APR <strong>Lending</strong><br />

Source: HAC tabulation of 2004 HMDA data.<br />

Figure 2: Map of Persistent Poverty Counties<br />

Source: Map prepared by ERS from U.S. Census Bureau data.


4 C A R S E Y I N S T I T U T E<br />

Figure 3. HALs by Race and Ethnicity<br />

Source: HAC tabulations of 2004 HMDA data<br />

of all rural HALs, minorities were much more likely to<br />

receive HALs than Whites. The proportion of HALs for rural<br />

minorities far exceeds that for rural non-Hispanic Whites.<br />

As shown in Figure 3, slightly less than one-third of all rural<br />

Latino and Native American borrowers received HALs in<br />

2004. Almost half (46.5 percent) of all rural African-American<br />

borrowers received a HAL. In comparison, less than 17<br />

percent of rural non-Hispanic White borrowers received<br />

high APR mortgage loans as reported by HMDA.<br />

Manufactured Housing<br />

Figure 4. Percent of rural property type with high cost loan<br />

One housing sector in rural America that is particularly tied<br />

to high APR lending is manufactured housing, which represents<br />

15 percent of the rural housing stock.<br />

The vast majority of manufactured housing continues to<br />

be financed using personal property loans, which do not<br />

have the same consumer protections as mortgage loans. Personal<br />

property loans allow borrowers to purchase a manufactured<br />

home with little or no down payment; however, the<br />

rates and terms are often significantly higher than conventional<br />

mortgages.<br />

Lenders that do make mortgage loans for manufactured<br />

homes impose stricter underwriting standards than do<br />

personal property lenders. Many mortgage lenders require<br />

manufactured homes to be placed on permanent foundations<br />

and on land that is privately owned. These requirements<br />

may be beneficial to the borrower in the long run but<br />

often increase the initial cost of the home.<br />

For those rural residents who took out a real estate loan,<br />

as reported in HMDA data, to purchase their manufactured<br />

homes in 2004, 50.7 percent received HALs (See Figure 4).<br />

The Effects of <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> in<br />

Rural Communities<br />

The Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong> (2001) estimates that<br />

predatory mortgage lending practices cost borrowers at<br />

minimum $9.1 billion annually. a It has been demonstrated<br />

that certain loan term characteristics (e.g. balloon payments<br />

and prepayment penalties) substantially increase the likelihood<br />

of foreclosure, and can jeopardize homeownership<br />

for those homeowners. b While there has been little research<br />

on the impact of predatory lending in rural communities,<br />

several studies have demonstrated the financial and physical<br />

impact predatory mortgage loans have on central city residents<br />

and neighborhoods. In addition to stripping the equity<br />

of individual homeowners and charging the most in terms of<br />

interest and fees to those who can least afford it, predatory<br />

mortgages can have significant community impacts as they<br />

can lead to increased foreclosures and vacant housing units<br />

(ACORN 2000).<br />

Research has shown that rural borrowers are more likely<br />

than those in urban areas to be subjected to prepayment<br />

penalties. 12 One study showed that in 2002, rural subprime<br />

borrowers were six percent more likely than urban borrowers<br />

to have a loan that included a prepayment penalty with<br />

a term of at least two years (CRL 2004). More tellingly, rural<br />

subprime borrowers were 20 percent more likely in 2002 to<br />

take out a mortgage with a prepayment penalty carrying a<br />

term of five or more years than urban borrowers.<br />

Overall, 63 percent of rural subprime mortgage loans<br />

imposed a prepayment penalty on borrowers with a twoyear<br />

penalty period. And 39 percent of all rural subprime<br />

mortgages studied had pre-payment penalties carrying terms<br />

of three years or longer (CRL 2004).<br />

Source: HAC tabulations of 2004 HMDA data<br />

a<br />

Eric Stein. 2001. Quantifying the Economic Cost of <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong>.<br />

Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>, Durham, NC.<br />

b<br />

Quercia, Stegman, and Davis. 2005. The Impact of <strong>Predatory</strong> Loan Terms<br />

on Subprime Foreclosures: The Special Case of Prepayment Penalties and


C A R S E Y I N S T I T U T E 5<br />

Conclusion and Recommendations<br />

A home is the most valuable asset for most low-income<br />

rural residents, as it is for most Americans. <strong>Predatory</strong> loans<br />

diminish the value of homeownership because they strip<br />

equity and undermine families’ ability to build assets. As<br />

discussed, although rural residents receive HALs at only<br />

slightly higher percentages than urban homebuyers, in rural<br />

areas, minorities are significantly more likely than whites to<br />

receive these loans.<br />

To protect the benefits of homeownership, national and<br />

state officials should adopt and enforce policies that better<br />

regulate supprime lending terms, monitor lending and<br />

real estate practices in this growing sector, and educate and<br />

protect borrowers.<br />

Needed Federal Action<br />

The Homeownership and Equity Protection Act (HOEPA),<br />

which passed in 1994, applies to all lenders in all states,<br />

while preserving the authority of individual states to enact<br />

laws that provide more rigorous consumer protections. 13<br />

Recent attempts to pass new anti-predatory legislation at<br />

the federal level are conflicted over preserving state control<br />

versus creating uniform federal standards that preempt state<br />

law.<br />

The mortgage industry has pushed strongly for uniform<br />

standards and federal preemption of state laws – focusing<br />

on H.R. 1295, sponsored by U.S. Reps. Bob Ney and Paul<br />

Kanjorski. Although the industry argues that complying with<br />

a myriad of state laws is costly, research by the Center for<br />

Responsible <strong>Lending</strong> has shown the cost of such compliance<br />

to be approximately $1 per mortgage transaction. 14<br />

Many advocates for low and moderate income families<br />

support a strong federal law that does not preempt stronger<br />

state laws; one example cited is H.R. 1182, sponsored by U.S.<br />

Reps. Brad Miller, Melvin Watt and Barney Frank. These<br />

groups argue that states need the ability to change their laws<br />

quickly to respond to changing markets and stamp out abusive<br />

practices that may differ from state to state.<br />

The Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong> has made recommendations<br />

to address unfair lending to racial and ethnic<br />

minorities in both rural and urban areas. Those recommendations<br />

call for stricter oversight of yield spread premiums,<br />

which encourage mortgage brokers to steer borrowers into<br />

subprime loans; requiring lenders and brokers to offer only<br />

loans that are suitable and reasonably advantageous for<br />

a given borrower; giving regulators wider authority and<br />

adequate resources to fully enforce fair lending laws; and<br />

creating incentives and new policies to ensure that minority<br />

borrowers are fairly served. 15<br />

Policymakers should also consider the following recommendations:<br />

• In addition to anti-predatory lending laws, Congress<br />

should consider strengthening the Community Reinvestment<br />

Act. CRA has been a critical tool used by local communities<br />

to encourage and increase access to affordable<br />

lending products. More effective use of the CRA process<br />

in rural communities and a strengthening of the law<br />

could result in more affordable lending products targeted<br />

to rural borrowers and less reliance on subprime products.<br />

• Government agencies, including the U.S. Department of<br />

Housing and Urban Development, private lenders, and<br />

other stakeholders should collaborate to fund, design,<br />

and implement effective, independent housing counseling<br />

programs and materials for low-income borrowers<br />

considering subprime loans. Federal regulators could<br />

stimulate banks to help fund these activities through the<br />

Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) examinations or<br />

through incentives. 16<br />

• The federal government should require small banks and<br />

those headquartered in non-metropolitan areas, which<br />

are now exempt from many reporting requirements<br />

under HMDA, to comply with proposed new reporting<br />

requirements in order to provide a full picture of lending<br />

practices in rural areas. Rural communities would then<br />

have a better understanding of lending trends and activity<br />

and would be better prepared to address lending abuses.<br />

Needed State Actions<br />

While federal policy can be an important tool to help protect<br />

borrowers from predatory mortgage lending, it should not<br />

preempt state policy. In passing anti-predatory legislation,<br />

some states 17 have closed loopholes in HOEPA and placed<br />

limits on abusive loans and practices. In general, the state<br />

laws attempt to:<br />

• Reduce excessive points and fees that strip equity from<br />

borrowers. This is usually done by reducing the percentage<br />

of points and fees (from 8 to 5 percent) that define a<br />

high-cost loan and trigger additional consumer protections.<br />

Also, additional fees that are presently not counted<br />

are included in the total percentage.<br />

• Provide consumers with additional protections for highcost<br />

loans, such as requiring mandatory credit counseling,<br />

prohibiting pre-payment penalties, or prohibiting the<br />

financing of fees.<br />

• Require interest rates to reflect the risk of the loan rather<br />

than upfront points and fees that strip equity from borrowers.<br />

Interest rates are more transparent to consumers.


6 C A R S E Y I N S T I T U T E<br />

• Protect consumers in disputes with lenders. Some states<br />

prohibit mandatory arbitration, which tends to favor<br />

lenders; some give borrowers legal protections even if<br />

their mortgage is sold in the secondary market.<br />

• Require a net tangible benefit to the borrower in any refinance<br />

loan. This is designed to prevent loan flipping and<br />

equity drain through excessive fees.<br />

Other states should follow the lead of “best practice” states<br />

such as North Carolina and Massachusetts, and adopt similar<br />

policies to protect vulnerable homebuyers both in rural<br />

and non-rural communities in their states.<br />

References<br />

Association of Community Organizations for Reform Now<br />

(ACORN). 2000. “Separate and Unequal: <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> in<br />

America.” ACORN: Washington, DC.<br />

Berenbaum, David. The National Community Reinvestment<br />

Coalition. 2002. The Myths of Subprime <strong>Lending</strong>. Rural Voices,<br />

Spring 2002, p.7.<br />

Bocian, Debbie Gruenstein, Keith S. Ernst and Wen Li. 2006.<br />

“Unfair <strong>Lending</strong>: The Effect of Race and Ethnicity on the Price<br />

of Subprime Mortgages.” Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>:<br />

Durham, NC.<br />

Bradford, Calvin. 2002. “Risk or Race? Racial Disparities and the<br />

Subprime Refinance Market.” Center for Community Change:<br />

Washington, DC.<br />

Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>. 2005. “<strong>Predatory</strong> Payday <strong>Lending</strong><br />

Traps Borrowers.” Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>: Durham, NC.<br />

Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>. 2004. “Rural Borrowers More<br />

Likely to be Penalized for Refinancing Subprime Home Loans.”<br />

Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>: Durham, NC.<br />

Cedillos, Romano. 2004. “Payday loans: easy, convenient—and<br />

pricey.” Tucson Citizen.<br />

Goldstein, Deborah. 1999. “Understanding <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong>:<br />

Moving Towards a Common Definition and Workable Solutions.”<br />

Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University:<br />

Cambridge, MA.<br />

Housing Assistance Council. 2005. Moving Home. Housing<br />

Assistance Council: Washington, DC.<br />

Quercia, Roberto G, Michael Stegman, and Walter Davis. 2005.<br />

“The Impact of <strong>Predatory</strong> Loan Terms on Subprime Foreclosures:<br />

The Special Case of Prepayment Penalties and Balloon Payments.”<br />

Center for Community Capitalism: Chapel Hill.<br />

Squires, Gregory D. 2005. “<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong>: Redlining in<br />

Reverse.” [online]. Available from www.nhi.org/online/issues/139/<br />

redlining.html.<br />

Temkin, Kenneth, Jennifer E. H. Johnson, and Diane Levy. 2002.<br />

“Subprime Markets, the Role of GSEs, and Risk-Based Pricing.”<br />

The Urban Institute: Washington, DC.<br />

U.S. Department of Agriculture. Economic Research Service<br />

(USDA ERS). 1997. “Credit in Rural America.” Agricultural<br />

Economic Report No. 749. USDA ERS: Washington, DC.<br />

Endnotes<br />

1<br />

Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>. 2004. Rural Borrowers More<br />

Likely to be Penalized for Refinancing Subprime Home Loans.<br />

Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>. Durham, NC.<br />

2<br />

Goldstein, Deborah. 1999. Understanding <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong>:<br />

Moving Towards a Common Definition and Workable Solutions.<br />

Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University:<br />

Cambridge, MA.<br />

3<br />

The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation reports that while 56<br />

percent of the nation’s banks are headquartered in nonmetro areas,<br />

rural counties have an average of 4.33 banking firms compared to<br />

10.90 for urban counties. See, http://www.ers.usda.gov/publications/RCAT/ract93i.pdf,<br />

for more information.<br />

4<br />

Quercia, Roberto G, Michael Stegman, and Walter Davis. 2005.<br />

The Impact of <strong>Predatory</strong> Loan Terms on Subprime Foreclosures:<br />

The Special Case of Prepayment Penalties and Balloon Payments.<br />

Center for Community Capitalism: Chapel Hill.<br />

5<br />

These data are reported through HMDA using the “rate spread”<br />

variable.<br />

6<br />

The Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA), enacted by Congress<br />

in 1975 and implemented by the Federal Reserve Board’s Regilation<br />

C, requires lending institutions to report public loan data.<br />

7<br />

Berenbaum, David. 2002. The National Community Reinvestment<br />

Coalition. The Myths of Subprime <strong>Lending</strong>. Rural Voices, Spring<br />

2002, p.7.<br />

8<br />

Squires, Gregory D. 2005. “<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong>: Redlining in<br />

Reverse.” [online]. Available from www.nhi.org/online/issues/139/<br />

redlining.html.<br />

9<br />

For the most comprehensive analysis of predatory lending<br />

targeted to racial and ethnic populations, see Gruenstein, Debbie,<br />

et al. 2006. Unfair <strong>Lending</strong>: The effect of Race and Ethnicity on the<br />

Price of Subprime Mortgages. Durham, NC: Center for Responsible<br />

<strong>Lending</strong>. Also see, Association of Community Organizations for<br />

Reform Now (ACORN). 2000. “Separate and Unequal: <strong>Predatory</strong><br />

<strong>Lending</strong> in America.” ACORN: Washington, D.C.<br />

10<br />

Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. 2004. Separate and Unequal:<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> in America. ACORN: Washington, DC.<br />

11<br />

The data reflect HAC’s analysis of 2004 HMDA data and “rural<br />

counties” are nonmetro counties. Nonmetro counties refer to places<br />

defined by the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) as nonmetropolitan<br />

in 2003. Nonmetropolitan areas are those counties<br />

that lie outside core based statistical areas.


C A R S E Y I N S T I T U T E 7<br />

12<br />

Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>. 2004. Rural Borrowers More<br />

Likely to be Penalized for Refinancing Subprime Home Loans.<br />

http://www.responsiblelending.org/pdfs/kf-Rural_Borrowers-0904.<br />

pdf<br />

13<br />

These best practice states include North Carolina, New Mexico,<br />

and Massachusetts.<br />

14<br />

Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>. July 2005. Strong Compliance<br />

Systems Support Profitable <strong>Lending</strong> While Reducing <strong>Predatory</strong><br />

Practices. Issue Paper No. 10. Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>.<br />

15<br />

For more information, see the Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong><br />

2006 report “Unfair <strong>Lending</strong>: the Effect of Race and Ethnicity on<br />

the Price of Subprime Mortgages.” This report can be found on the<br />

Center’s website at: http://www.responsiblelending.org/pdfs/rr011-<br />

Unfair_<strong>Lending</strong>-0506.pdf<br />

16<br />

The FHLB subsidizes the interest rates for advances (loans) and<br />

provides direct subsidies to FHLBank System members engaged<br />

in lending for affordable housing. The 12 FHLBanks reserve 10<br />

percent of their collective net income or $100 million, whichever is<br />

greater, for use in the Affordable Housing Program.<br />

17<br />

These states include North Carolina, New Mexico, Massachusetts.<br />

Acknowledgements<br />

We thank Josh Silver and Jim Campen for their helpful external<br />

review of this policy brief and Amy Seif of the Carsey Institute,<br />

Priscilla Salant, and the Hatcher Group for editorial assistance.<br />

The Carsey Institute appreciates early review by the National<br />

Community Reinvestment Coalition (NCRC); however, NCRC is<br />

not responsible for the findings of this research.<br />

Authors<br />

Theresa Singleton, Director of Research and Information, Housing<br />

Assistance Council. Theresa@ruralhome.org<br />

Lance George, Research Associate, Housing Assistance Council.<br />

Lance@ruralhome.org<br />

Carla Dickstein, Senior Vice-President for Research and<br />

Policy Development, Coastal Enterprises, Inc. cbd@ceimaine.org<br />

Hannah Thomas, Research Associate, Coastal Enterprises, Inc.<br />

Hlt@ceimaine.org<br />

The Housing Assistance Council (HAC), founded in 1971, is a<br />

nonprofit corporation that supports the development of<br />

rural low-income housing nationwide. HAC provides technical<br />

housing services, loans from a revolving fund, housing program<br />

and policy assistance, research and demonstration projects, and<br />

training and information services. Coastal Enterprises, Inc. (CEI) is<br />

a community development finance institution that supports small<br />

businesses and affordable housing development primarily in Maine<br />

through financing, technical assistance, and workforce development.<br />

The Carsey Institute partners with HAC and CEI to provide<br />

information on predatory lending to policymakers, practitioners<br />

and the general public.


8 C A R S E Y I N S T I T U T E<br />

BUILDING KNOWLEDGE FOR FAMILIES AND COMMUNITIES<br />

IN THE 21st CENTURY.<br />

The Carsey Institute at the University of New Hampshire<br />

conducts independent, interdisciplinary research and<br />

communicates its findings to policymakers, practitioners<br />

and the general public.<br />

Huddleston Hall<br />

73 Main Street<br />

Durham, NH 03824<br />

(603) 862-2821<br />

www.carseyinstitute.unh.edu<br />

The Carsey Institute Reports on Rural America are supported<br />

by the Annie E. Casey Foundation’s initiative to strengthen<br />

rural families, the Ford Foundation, and the W.K. Kellogg<br />

Foundation.


The Persistence of <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong>:<br />

C A R S E Y I N S T I T U T E 9<br />

A Case Study from Maine<br />

Introduction<br />

In 2005, Coastal Enterprises, Inc. (CEI) and the Center for Responsible<br />

<strong>Lending</strong> (CRL) 1 , conducted the first systematic investigation<br />

of the nature and extent of predatory lending in Maine. 2 The<br />

impetus for the study was a concern that Maine citizens were not<br />

receiving the same protections against predatory lending practices<br />

that are available in other states such as Massachusetts, New Mexico<br />

and North Carolina.<br />

The research examined trends in Maine’s subprime mortgage<br />

market and the characteristics of loans made in Maine from 2000<br />

through 2005 to determine if they had predatory characteristics.<br />

A number of data sources were used, including available empirical<br />

data on the subprime market 3 ; publicly available foreclosure<br />

records and lien histories; and interviews with various stakeholders<br />

and borrowers. In addition, the researchers reviewed the relevant<br />

laws and regulations in Maine’s Consumer Credit Code to answer<br />

a basic question: Do current laws in Maine provide an appropriate<br />

framework to regulate subprime mortgage lending, given the lending<br />

practices revealed by the research?<br />

Key Findings of Maine’s Subprime Mortgage Market<br />

Like other parts of the country, Maine’s subprime mortgage market<br />

has grown dramatically. Between 2000 and 2004, its subprime<br />

market grew 436 percent by dollar volume. In 2004, it topped<br />

$1 billion with about 8000 loans. In 2003 subprime loans (excluding<br />

subprime loans for manufactured housing) were almost 10<br />

percent of the total Maine mortgage market. Over 30 percent of<br />

all subprime loans made in Maine by lenders on HUD’s Subprime<br />

Lender List in 2003 4 were from two out-of-state non-bank lenders,<br />

Option One Mortgage Corporation and Ameriquest.<br />

Mainers obtain a higher percentage of their subprime loans in<br />

the form of cash-out refinances than do borrowers in any other<br />

state. Between January 2004 and May 2005, 65 percent of the state’s<br />

subprime mortgage market represented cash-out refinances, 5 which<br />

is where most abuses in the subprime mortgage market typically<br />

occur. During the same period, only 28 percent of subprime<br />

mortgage loans in Maine were used for home purchases, the lowest<br />

in the nation. This trend is consistent with Maine’s high home<br />

ownership rate, rising property values in many parts of the state,<br />

rising consumer debt, pockets of economic distress, and aging<br />

population—conditions that make it vulnerable to predatory lending<br />

practices.<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> lending is evident in Maine’s subprime loans. An<br />

examination of subprime mortgage loans shows the following<br />

predatory characteristics:<br />

• Steering. A conservative analysis of data suggests that at least<br />

15 percent of the subprime mortgages in Maine between 2003<br />

and 2005 went to families who could have qualified for a less<br />

expensive loan.<br />

• Prepayment Penalties with terms greater than 24 months have<br />

increased, albeit only marginally, since the passage of Maine’s<br />

2003 anti-predatory lending law from 12 percent of subprime<br />

originations to 15 percent.<br />

• Abusive lending terms in subprime foreclosure records. Subprime<br />

records in four district courts showed loan terms strongly<br />

associated with predatory lending, including: mandatory<br />

arbitration (17 percent of records); prepayment penalties (11<br />

percent); points and fees over five percent; and evidence of flipping.<br />

In total, at least 26 percent of the records contained one or<br />

more of the following terms: mandatory arbitration, points and<br />

fees over five percent, or prepayment penalties. Most records<br />

did not document loan characteristics, so our findings very<br />

likely substantially under-report the extent of predatory lending<br />

characteristics.<br />

Stakeholders also described extensive debt consolidation driving<br />

a market for subprime loans with abusive loan terms, aggressive<br />

sales tactics and equity stripping. Interviewees included mortgage<br />

brokers, bank and credit union lenders, bankruptcy trustees,<br />

bankruptcy attorneys, housing counselors and borrowers. Those<br />

interviewed also noted general concerns about inflated appraisals;<br />

“bottom feeders 6 “ targeting borrowers in bankruptcy; steering and<br />

flipping. One of the borrowers interviewed lost about $100,000 in<br />

equity to predatory practices, and five of the nine borrowers interviewed<br />

were either in, or had gone through, the foreclosure process.<br />

Characteristics of Subprime Mortgage Market in Rural<br />

Maine<br />

Between January 2004 and May 2005, 52 percent of the Maine<br />

subprime originations were in rural parts of the state, while only 42<br />

percent of Maine’s population is rural. Maine ranked fourth in the<br />

nation for the concentration of subprime mortgage loans in rural<br />

areas. Maine’s rural counties that are further away from more urban<br />

areas of southern Maine had higher concentrations of subprime<br />

mortgage loans as a percentage of total mortgage loans. The highest<br />

concentrations of subprime loans were in some of the poorest<br />

rural “rim counties” – Somerset, Washington and Piscataquis. This<br />

is consistent with the findings that rural communities have fewer<br />

lending options and are more susceptible to subprime lenders.<br />

However, the research could not determine whether the high concentration<br />

of subprime loans in rural areas reflected a higher risk<br />

for these loans.<br />

Most of the data that indicate predatory lending characteristics<br />

of subprime loans are not available by rural areas. What data are<br />

Table 1: Summary of Multiple Refinances seen in Portland,<br />

South Paris, Newport and Lincoln County District Courts<br />

Registries of Deeds Sample<br />

District Number of Refinances Multiple Total Percentage<br />

Court lien histories where interest refinances by possible of possible<br />

reviewed for rate increased subprime flips flips for<br />

subprime between lender sample<br />

foreclosures subprime loans<br />

Portland 30 3 7 10 33<br />

Lincoln 11 3 1 4 36<br />

South Paris 20 0 5 5 20<br />

Newport 15 0 2 2 13


available come from 357 foreclosure and lien records determined<br />

10 to be Csubprime A R S E Y loans I N 7 Sin Tthree I T Urural T E county courthouses in Lincoln<br />

County, South Paris, and Newport. <strong>Predatory</strong> lending characteristics<br />

evident in these records included excessive points and fees,<br />

mandatory arbitration clauses, prepayment penalties over two<br />

years, and multiple refinances that suggest possible flipping 8 of<br />

loans with no net tangible benefit to the borrower as shown below.<br />

Conclusion and Recommendations<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> mortgage lending in Maine leads to lost wealth for families<br />

and, too often, lost homes. A 2001 study estimated that Maine<br />

lost $23.4 million in 2000 through equity stripping practices. 9 This<br />

figure does not include foreclosure losses. One out of five subprime<br />

mortgages originated in 1999 entered foreclosure by 2005, giving<br />

Maine the highest cumulative rate in New England for that period. 10<br />

It is not clear how much of that figure is a result of predatory<br />

mortgage lending, but as cited above, national research has shown<br />

a higher risk of foreclosure from some predatory mortgage lending<br />

practices.<br />

The study found that Maine’s current legal framework fails to<br />

protect its families from the abusive lending practices identified in<br />

the research. A so-called anti-predatory lending law passed in 2003<br />

(PL49) has not provided adequate protections, and in fact legalized<br />

some of the abusive practices identified in the national Household<br />

and Beneficial Finance Corporations lawsuit settled by the Maine<br />

Attorney General in 2003. Additionally, many of the practices<br />

alleged in the lawsuit such as excessive points and fees, prepayment<br />

penalties, abusive use of open-ended credit, and flipping are<br />

largely legal in today’s Maine market.<br />

Protections against predatory lending could be substantially<br />

strengthened through state legislative action. Maine regulates<br />

eighty-nine percent of recognized subprime lenders identified in<br />

the HUD Subprime Lender List. In addition, Maine regulates all<br />

mortgage brokers. As such, Maine can draw on the experience of a<br />

number of best practice states with strong anti-predatory laws, such<br />

as North Carolina, New Mexico and Massachusetts, to improve its<br />

legislation and ensure that more Maine families hold on to their<br />

homes and their hard-earned wealth acquired through home equity.<br />

A recent study by the Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong> of 28 state<br />

reforms found that strong state laws are working well to prevent<br />

predatory lending. Furthermore, borrowers have ready access to<br />

subprime credit in these states., and borrowers pay about the same<br />

or lower interest rates for subprime mortgages. 11 Recommended<br />

changes in Maine’s Consumer Credit Code are as follows.<br />

Redefine what is meant by “high-cost” loans and provide more<br />

protections for these loans<br />

The percentage of points and fees that trigger a “high-cost” loan<br />

should be reduced, more types of fees must be counted, and open<br />

ended loans, such as a line of credit, must be subject to the definition.<br />

Extra protections for “high–cost” loans include mandatory<br />

credit counseling, prohibiting pre-payment penalties, and prohibiting<br />

the financing of fees.<br />

Ensure appropriate recourse for consumers if they have problems<br />

with their loans<br />

Mandatory arbitration should be prohibited, thus ensuring that<br />

borrowers can pursue a dispute with the lender through the court<br />

system. Assignee liability provisions should be adopted that allow<br />

borrowers to pursue justice from secondary market lenders who<br />

buy their loans.<br />

Require that loans that are refinanced have a net tangible benefit<br />

to the consumer.<br />

This provision will prevent loan flipping and stripping of equity<br />

from borrowers through excessive points and fees.<br />

These recommendations provide more transparency of the true<br />

costs of loans to consumers and more protections. None of the<br />

recommendations prevent a lender from charging whatever points<br />

or fees or interest rates it considers necessary. If the threshold of a<br />

high-cost loan is lowered, the lender can still make a loan that exceeds<br />

the threshold but would trigger additional consumer protections.<br />

While strong legislation is essential, solving the problem of<br />

predatory mortgage lending requires complementary efforts such<br />

as consumer/financial education and better outreach by responsible<br />

lenders to borrowers who might otherwise fall into the hands of<br />

predatory lenders. However, such actions will have little impact<br />

unless they are supported by effective policies to help ensure that<br />

responsible lenders can compete in Maine.<br />

Endnotes<br />

By Carla Dickstein and Hannah Thomas,<br />

adapted from Dickstein et al (2006).<br />

1<br />

CEI, based in Wiscasset, Maine, is a community development corporation<br />

(CDC) and community development finance institution<br />

(CDFI). CRL is a subsidiary of Self-Help Community Credit Union<br />

headquartered n Durahm, North Carolina, which is also a CDFI.<br />

2<br />

See Carla Dickstein, Hannah Thomas and Uriah King. 2006.<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> Mortgages in Maine: Recent Trenads and the Persistence<br />

of Abusive <strong>Lending</strong> in the Subprime Mortgage Market. Coastal<br />

Enterprises, Inc., Wiscasset, ME. This study was supported by the<br />

Annie E. Casey Foundation, Maine’s Attorney General and AARP.<br />

3<br />

These included data collected under the Home Mortgage<br />

Disclosure Act (HMDA), from the Mortgage Bankers’ Association<br />

and most important, from an industry database that compiles<br />

self-reported data from the mortgage industry on the characteristics<br />

of loans, described in Dickstein et al (2006).<br />

4<br />

Data is from the HUD 2003 list of subprime lenders.<br />

5<br />

A cash-out refinance gives the mortgagor cash back after paying<br />

off the mortgage , any junior mortgage and settlement costs. The<br />

cash paid out comes out of the equity in the house and is often used<br />

to pay off credit card debt.<br />

6<br />

These individuals offer to get people out of Chapter 13 bankruptcy<br />

by refinancing the loan at outrageous terms that homeowners<br />

cannot afford. In almost every case, the loan leads eventually to<br />

foreclosure, and the excessive fees charged in this last-ditch refinancing<br />

strip away any equity the homeowner may have had left in<br />

the house.<br />

7<br />

Subprime loans were determined by the lenders’ inclusion in the<br />

HUD Subprime Lender List, and in the top 25 list from Inside B<br />

&C <strong>Lending</strong>, an industry publication.<br />

8<br />

In order to fully assess flipping, we would have to review every<br />

borrower’s loan documents and loan history. Hence we refer to<br />

“possible flips.”<br />

9<br />

See Eric Stein. 2001. Quantifying the Economic Cost of <strong>Predatory</strong><br />

<strong>Lending</strong>. Center for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>, Durham, NC.<br />

10<br />

This finding is from the industry database analysis. Details of this<br />

database are described in Farris and Richardson, “The Geography<br />

of Supbrime Mortgage Prepayment Penalty Patterns.” Housing<br />

Policy Debate 15 (3) 687-714.<br />

11<br />

See Wei Li and Keith Ernst. 2006. The Best Value in the Subprime<br />

Market: State <strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> Reforms. Durham, NC: Center<br />

for Responsible <strong>Lending</strong>. This peer-reviewed study used statistical<br />

analysis to compare states with anti-predatory lending laws to<br />

states without these laws.


Page 156 of 181


Advocacy Foundation Publishers<br />

Page 157 of 181


Advocacy Foundation Publishers<br />

The e-Advocate Quarterly<br />

Page 158 of 181


Issue Title Quarterly<br />

Vol. I 2015 The Fundamentals<br />

I<br />

The ComeUnity ReEngineering<br />

Project Initiative<br />

Q-1 2015<br />

II The Adolescent Law Group Q-2 2015<br />

III<br />

Landmark Cases in US<br />

Juvenile Justice (PA)<br />

Q-3 2015<br />

IV The First Amendment Project Q-4 2015<br />

Vol. II 2016 Strategic Development<br />

V The Fourth Amendment Project Q-1 2016<br />

VI<br />

Landmark Cases in US<br />

Juvenile Justice (NJ)<br />

Q-2 2016<br />

VII Youth Court Q-3 2016<br />

VIII<br />

The Economic Consequences of Legal<br />

Decision-Making<br />

Q-4 2016<br />

Vol. III 2017 Sustainability<br />

IX The Sixth Amendment Project Q-1 2017<br />

X<br />

The Theological Foundations of<br />

US Law & Government<br />

Q-2 2017<br />

XI The Eighth Amendment Project Q-3 2017<br />

XII<br />

The EB-5 Investor<br />

Immigration Project*<br />

Q-4 2017<br />

Vol. IV 2018 Collaboration<br />

XIII Strategic Planning Q-1 2018<br />

XIV<br />

The Juvenile Justice<br />

Legislative Reform Initiative<br />

Q-2 2018<br />

XV The Advocacy Foundation Coalition Q-3 2018<br />

Page 159 of 181


XVI<br />

for Drug-Free Communities<br />

Landmark Cases in US<br />

Juvenile Justice (GA)<br />

Q-4 2018<br />

Page 160 of 181


Issue Title Quarterly<br />

Vol. V 2019 Organizational Development<br />

XVII The Board of Directors Q-1 2019<br />

XVIII The Inner Circle Q-2 2019<br />

XIX Staff & Management Q-3 2019<br />

XX Succession Planning Q-4 2019<br />

XXI The Budget* Bonus #1<br />

XXII Data-Driven Resource Allocation* Bonus #2<br />

Vol. VI 2020 Missions<br />

XXIII Critical Thinking Q-1 2020<br />

XXIV<br />

The Advocacy Foundation<br />

Endowments Initiative Project<br />

Q-2 2020<br />

XXV International Labor Relations Q-3 2020<br />

XXVI Immigration Q-4 2020<br />

Vol. VII 2021 Community Engagement<br />

XXVII<br />

The 21 st Century Charter Schools<br />

Initiative<br />

Q-1 2021<br />

XXVIII The All-Sports Ministry @ ... Q-2 2021<br />

XXIX Lobbying for Nonprofits Q-3 2021<br />

XXX<br />

XXXI<br />

Advocacy Foundation Missions -<br />

Domestic<br />

Advocacy Foundation Missions -<br />

International<br />

Q-4 2021<br />

Bonus<br />

Page 161 of 181


Vol. VIII<br />

2022 ComeUnity ReEngineering<br />

XXXII<br />

The Creative & Fine Arts Ministry<br />

@ The Foundation<br />

Q-1 2022<br />

XXXIII The Advisory Council & Committees Q-2 2022<br />

XXXIV<br />

The Theological Origins<br />

of Contemporary Judicial Process<br />

Q-3 2022<br />

XXXV The Second Chance Ministry @ ... Q-4 2022<br />

Vol. IX 2023 Legal Reformation<br />

XXXVI The Fifth Amendment Project Q-1 2023<br />

XXXVII The Judicial Re-Engineering Initiative Q-2 2023<br />

XXXVIII<br />

The Inner-Cities Strategic<br />

Revitalization Initiative<br />

Q-3 2023<br />

XXXVIX Habeas Corpus Q-4 2023<br />

Vol. X 2024 ComeUnity Development<br />

XXXVX<br />

The Inner-City Strategic<br />

Revitalization Plan<br />

Q-1 2024<br />

XXXVXI The Mentoring Initiative Q-2 2024<br />

XXXVXII The Violence Prevention Framework Q-3 2024<br />

XXXVXIII The Fatherhood Initiative Q-4 2024<br />

Vol. XI 2025 Public Interest<br />

XXXVXIV Public Interest Law Q-1 2025<br />

L (50) Spiritual Resource Development Q-2 2025<br />

Page 162 of 181


LI<br />

Nonprofit Confidentiality<br />

In The Age of Big Data<br />

Q-3 2025<br />

LII Interpreting The Facts Q-4 2025<br />

Vol. XII 2026 Poverty In America<br />

LIII<br />

American Poverty<br />

In The New Millennium<br />

Q-1 2026<br />

LIV Outcome-Based Thinking Q-2 2026<br />

LV Transformational Social Leadership Q-3 2026<br />

LVI The Cycle of Poverty Q-4 2026<br />

Vol. XIII 2027 Raising Awareness<br />

LVII ReEngineering Juvenile Justice Q-1 2027<br />

LVIII Corporations Q-2 2027<br />

LVIX The Prison Industrial Complex Q-3 2027<br />

LX Restoration of Rights Q-4 2027<br />

Vol. XIV 2028 Culturally Relevant Programming<br />

LXI Community Culture Q-1 2028<br />

LXII Corporate Culture Q-2 2028<br />

LXIII Strategic Cultural Planning Q-3 2028<br />

LXIV<br />

The Cross-Sector/ Coordinated<br />

Service Approach to Delinquency<br />

Prevention<br />

Q-4 2028<br />

Page 163 of 181


Vol. XV 2029 Inner-Cities Revitalization<br />

LXIV<br />

LXV<br />

LXVI<br />

Part I – Strategic Housing<br />

Revitalization<br />

(The Twenty Percent Profit Margin)<br />

Part II – Jobs Training, Educational<br />

Redevelopment<br />

and Economic Empowerment<br />

Part III - Financial Literacy<br />

and Sustainability<br />

Q-1 2029<br />

Q-2 2029<br />

Q-3 2029<br />

LXVII Part IV – Solutions for Homelessness Q-4 2029<br />

LXVIII<br />

The Strategic Home Mortgage<br />

Initiative<br />

Bonus<br />

Vol. XVI 2030 Sustainability<br />

LXVIII Social Program Sustainability Q-1 2030<br />

LXIX<br />

The Advocacy Foundation<br />

Endowments Initiative<br />

Q-2 2030<br />

LXX Capital Gains Q-3 2030<br />

LXXI Sustainability Investments Q-4 2030<br />

Vol. XVII 2031 The Justice Series<br />

LXXII Distributive Justice Q-1 2031<br />

LXXIII Retributive Justice Q-2 2031<br />

LXXIV Procedural Justice Q-3 2031<br />

LXXV (75) Restorative Justice Q-4 2031<br />

LXXVI Unjust Legal Reasoning Bonus<br />

Page 164 of 181


Vol. XVIII 2032 Public Policy<br />

LXXVII Public Interest Law Q-1 2032<br />

LXXVIII Reforming Public Policy Q-2 2032<br />

LXXVIX ... Q-3 2032<br />

LXXVX ... Q-4 2032<br />

Page 165 of 181


The e-Advocate Monthly Review<br />

2018<br />

Transformational Problem Solving January 2018<br />

The Advocacy Foundation February 2018<br />

Opioid Initiative<br />

Native-American Youth March 2018<br />

In the Juvenile Justice System<br />

Barriers to Reducing Confinement April 2018<br />

Latino and Hispanic Youth May 2018<br />

In the Juvenile Justice System<br />

Social Entrepreneurship June 2018<br />

The Economic Consequences of<br />

Homelessness in America S.Ed – June 2018<br />

African-American Youth July 2018<br />

In the Juvenile Justice System<br />

Gang Deconstruction August 2018<br />

Social Impact Investing September 2018<br />

Opportunity Youth: October 2018<br />

Disenfranchised Young People<br />

The Economic Impact of Social November 2018<br />

of Social Programs Development<br />

Gun Control December 2018<br />

2019<br />

The U.S. Stock Market January 2019<br />

Prison-Based Gerrymandering February 2019<br />

Literacy-Based Prison Construction March 2019<br />

Children of Incarcerated Parents April 2019<br />

Page 166 of 181


African-American Youth in The May 2019<br />

Juvenile Justice System<br />

Racial Profiling June 2019<br />

Mass Collaboration July 2019<br />

Concentrated Poverty August 2019<br />

De-Industrialization September 2019<br />

Overcoming Dyslexia October 2019<br />

Overcoming Attention Deficit November 2019<br />

The Gift of Adversity December 2019<br />

2020<br />

The Gift of Hypersensitivity January 2020<br />

The Gift of Introspection February 2020<br />

The Gift of Introversion March 2020<br />

The Gift of Spirituality April 2020<br />

The Gift of Transformation May 2020<br />

Property Acquisition for<br />

Organizational Sustainability June 2020<br />

Investing for Organizational<br />

Sustainability July 2020<br />

Biblical Law & Justice TLFA August 2020<br />

Gentrification AF September 2020<br />

Environmental Racism NpA October 2020<br />

Law for The Poor AF November 2020<br />

…<br />

Page 167 of 181


2021<br />

Biblically Responsible Investing TLFA – January 2021<br />

International Criminal Procedure LMI – February 2021<br />

Spiritual Rights TLFA – March 2021<br />

The Theology of Missions TLFA – April 2021<br />

Legal Evangelism, Intelligence,<br />

Reconnaissance & Missions LMI – May 2021<br />

The Law of War LMI – June 2021<br />

Generational Progression AF – July 2021<br />

<strong>Predatory</strong> <strong>Lending</strong> AF – August 2021<br />

…<br />

Page 168 of 181


The e-Advocate Quarterly<br />

Special Editions<br />

Crowdfunding Winter-Spring 2017<br />

Social Media for Nonprofits October 2017<br />

Mass Media for Nonprofits November 2017<br />

The Opioid Crisis in America: January 2018<br />

Issues in Pain Management<br />

The Opioid Crisis in America: February 2018<br />

The Drug Culture in the U.S.<br />

The Opioid Crisis in America: March 2018<br />

Drug Abuse Among Veterans<br />

The Opioid Crisis in America: April 2018<br />

Drug Abuse Among America’s<br />

Teens<br />

The Opioid Crisis in America: May 2018<br />

Alcoholism<br />

The Economic Consequences of June 2018<br />

Homelessness in The US<br />

The Economic Consequences of July 2018<br />

Opioid Addiction in America<br />

Page 169 of 181


The e-Advocate Journal<br />

of Theological Jurisprudence<br />

Vol. I - 2017<br />

The Theological Origins of Contemporary Judicial Process<br />

Scriptural Application to The Model Criminal Code<br />

Scriptural Application for Tort Reform<br />

Scriptural Application to Juvenile Justice Reformation<br />

Vol. II - 2018<br />

Scriptural Application for The Canons of Ethics<br />

Scriptural Application to Contracts Reform<br />

& The Uniform Commercial Code<br />

Scriptural Application to The Law of Property<br />

Scriptural Application to The Law of Evidence<br />

Page 170 of 181


Legal Missions International<br />

Page 171 of 181


Issue Title Quarterly<br />

Vol. I 2015<br />

I<br />

II<br />

God’s Will and The 21 st Century<br />

Democratic Process<br />

The Community<br />

Engagement Strategy<br />

Q-1 2015<br />

Q-2 2015<br />

III Foreign Policy Q-3 2015<br />

IV<br />

Public Interest Law<br />

in The New Millennium<br />

Q-4 2015<br />

Vol. II 2016<br />

V Ethiopia Q-1 2016<br />

VI Zimbabwe Q-2 2016<br />

VII Jamaica Q-3 2016<br />

VIII Brazil Q-4 2016<br />

Vol. III 2017<br />

IX India Q-1 2017<br />

X Suriname Q-2 2017<br />

XI The Caribbean Q-3 2017<br />

XII United States/ Estados Unidos Q-4 2017<br />

Vol. IV 2018<br />

XIII Cuba Q-1 2018<br />

XIV Guinea Q-2 2018<br />

XV Indonesia Q-3 2018<br />

XVI Sri Lanka Q-4 2018<br />

Page 172 of 181


Vol. V 2019<br />

XVII Russia Q-1 2019<br />

XVIII Australia Q-2 2019<br />

XIV South Korea Q-3 2019<br />

XV Puerto Rico Q-4 2019<br />

Issue Title Quarterly<br />

Vol. VI 2020<br />

XVI Trinidad & Tobago Q-1 2020<br />

XVII Egypt Q-2 2020<br />

XVIII Sierra Leone Q-3 2020<br />

XIX South Africa Q-4 2020<br />

XX Israel Bonus<br />

Vol. VII 2021<br />

XXI Haiti Q-1 2021<br />

XXII Peru Q-2 2021<br />

XXIII Costa Rica Q-3 2021<br />

XXIV China Q-4 2021<br />

XXV Japan Bonus<br />

Vol VIII 2022<br />

XXVI Chile Q-1 2022<br />

Page 173 of 181


The e-Advocate Juvenile Justice Report<br />

______<br />

Vol. I – Juvenile Delinquency in The US<br />

Vol. II. – The Prison Industrial Complex<br />

Vol. III – Restorative/ Transformative Justice<br />

Vol. IV – The Sixth Amendment Right to The Effective Assistance of Counsel<br />

Vol. V – The Theological Foundations of Juvenile Justice<br />

Vol. VI – Collaborating to Eradicate Juvenile Delinquency<br />

Page 174 of 181


The e-Advocate Newsletter<br />

Genesis of The Problem<br />

Family Structure<br />

Societal Influences<br />

Evidence-Based Programming<br />

Strengthening Assets v. Eliminating Deficits<br />

2012 - Juvenile Delinquency in The US<br />

Introduction/Ideology/Key Values<br />

Philosophy/Application & Practice<br />

Expungement & Pardons<br />

Pardons & Clemency<br />

Examples/Best Practices<br />

2013 - Restorative Justice in The US<br />

2014 - The Prison Industrial Complex<br />

25% of the World's Inmates Are In the US<br />

The Economics of Prison Enterprise<br />

The Federal Bureau of Prisons<br />

The After-Effects of Incarceration/Individual/Societal<br />

The Fourth Amendment Project<br />

The Sixth Amendment Project<br />

The Eighth Amendment Project<br />

The Adolescent Law Group<br />

2015 - US Constitutional Issues In The New Millennium<br />

Page 175 of 181


2018 - The Theological Law Firm Academy<br />

The Theological Foundations of US Law & Government<br />

The Economic Consequences of Legal Decision-Making<br />

The Juvenile Justice Legislative Reform Initiative<br />

The EB-5 International Investors Initiative<br />

2017 - Organizational Development<br />

The Board of Directors<br />

The Inner Circle<br />

Staff & Management<br />

Succession Planning<br />

Bonus #1 The Budget<br />

Bonus #2 Data-Driven Resource Allocation<br />

2018 - Sustainability<br />

The Data-Driven Resource Allocation Process<br />

The Quality Assurance Initiative<br />

The Advocacy Foundation Endowments Initiative<br />

The Community Engagement Strategy<br />

2019 - Collaboration<br />

Critical Thinking for Transformative Justice<br />

International Labor Relations<br />

Immigration<br />

God's Will & The 21st Century Democratic Process<br />

The Community Engagement Strategy<br />

The 21st Century Charter Schools Initiative<br />

2020 - Community Engagement<br />

Page 176 of 181


Extras<br />

The Nonprofit Advisors Group Newsletters<br />

The 501(c)(3) Acquisition Process<br />

The Board of Directors<br />

The Gladiator Mentality<br />

Strategic Planning<br />

Fundraising<br />

501(c)(3) Reinstatements<br />

The Collaborative US/ International Newsletters<br />

How You Think Is Everything<br />

The Reciprocal Nature of Business Relationships<br />

Accelerate Your Professional Development<br />

The Competitive Nature of Grant Writing<br />

Assessing The Risks<br />

Page 177 of 181


Page 178 of 181


About The Author<br />

John C (Jack) Johnson III<br />

Founder & CEO<br />

Jack was educated at Temple University, in Philadelphia, Pennsylvania and Rutgers<br />

Law School, in Camden, New Jersey. In 1999, he moved to Atlanta, Georgia to pursue<br />

greater opportunities to provide Advocacy and Preventive Programmatic services for atrisk/<br />

at-promise young persons, their families, and Justice Professionals embedded in the<br />

Juvenile Justice process in order to help facilitate its transcendence into the 21 st Century.<br />

There, along with a small group of community and faith-based professionals, “The Advocacy Foundation, Inc." was conceived<br />

and developed over roughly a thirteen year period, originally chartered as a Juvenile Delinquency Prevention and Educational<br />

Support Services organization consisting of Mentoring, Tutoring, Counseling, Character Development, Community Change<br />

Management, Practitioner Re-Education & Training, and a host of related components.<br />

The Foundation’s Overarching Mission is “To help Individuals, Organizations, & Communities Achieve Their Full Potential”, by<br />

implementing a wide array of evidence-based proactive multi-disciplinary "Restorative & Transformative Justice" programs &<br />

projects currently throughout the northeast, southeast, and western international-waters regions, providing prevention and support<br />

services to at-risk/ at-promise youth, to young adults, to their families, and to Social Service, Justice and Mental<br />

Health professionals” everywhere. The Foundation has since relocated its headquarters to Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, and been<br />

expanded to include a three-tier mission.<br />

In addition to his work with the Foundation, Jack also served as an Adjunct Professor of Law & Business at National-Louis<br />

University of Atlanta (where he taught Political Science, Business & Legal Ethics, Labor & Employment Relations, and Critical<br />

Thinking courses to undergraduate and graduate level students). Jack has also served as Board President for a host of wellestablished<br />

and up & coming nonprofit organizations throughout the region, including “Visions Unlimited Community<br />

Development Systems, Inc.”, a multi-million dollar, award-winning, Violence Prevention and Gang Intervention Social Service<br />

organization in Atlanta, as well as Vice-Chair of the Georgia/ Metropolitan Atlanta Violence Prevention Partnership, a state-wide<br />

300 organizational member, violence prevention group led by the Morehouse School of Medicine, Emory University and The<br />

Original, Atlanta-Based, Martin Luther King Center.<br />

Attorney Johnson’s prior accomplishments include a wide-array of Professional Legal practice areas, including Private Firm,<br />

Corporate and Government postings, just about all of which yielded significant professional awards & accolades, the history and<br />

chronology of which are available for review online. Throughout his career, Jack has served a wide variety of for-profit<br />

corporations, law firms, and nonprofit organizations as Board Chairman, Secretary, Associate, and General Counsel since 1990.<br />

www.TheAdvocacyFoundation.org<br />

Clayton County Youth Services Partnership, Inc. – Chair; Georgia Violence Prevention Partnership, Inc – Vice Chair; Fayette<br />

County NAACP - Legal Redress Committee Chairman; Clayton County Fatherhood Initiative Partnership – Principal<br />

Investigator; Morehouse School of Medicine School of Community Health Feasibility Study - Steering Committee; Atlanta<br />

Violence Prevention Capacity Building Project – Project Partner; Clayton County Minister’s Conference, President 2006-2007;<br />

Liberty In Life Ministries, Inc. – Board Secretary; Young Adults Talk, Inc. – Board of Directors; ROYAL, Inc - Board of<br />

Directors; Temple University Alumni Association; Rutgers Law School Alumni Association; Sertoma International; Our<br />

Common Welfare Board of Directors – President)2003-2005; River’s Edge Elementary School PTA (Co-President); Summerhill<br />

Community Ministries; Outstanding Young Men of America; Employee of the Year; Academic All-American - Basketball;<br />

Church Trustee.<br />

Page 179 of 181


www.TheAdvocacyFoundation.org<br />

Page 180 of 181


Page 181 of 181

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!