07.01.2013 Views

hail shale - Institute of Directors

hail shale - Institute of Directors

hail shale - Institute of Directors

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Big Picture<br />

All <strong>hail</strong> <strong>shale</strong><br />

WINTER 2012/13


Big Picture<br />

Published three times a year by the <strong>Institute</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Directors</strong>, Big Picture draws on the expertise <strong>of</strong> the<br />

IoD Policy Unit and external contributors.<br />

The purpose <strong>of</strong> Big Picture is to:<br />

o Present leading-edge thinking;<br />

o Highlight key public policy issues affecting business;<br />

o Look over the horizon at strategic issues likely to<br />

have an impact on business in the future;<br />

o Provide an insight into public policy issues in an<br />

accessible format;<br />

o Suggest solutions to the ‘big picture’ questions facing<br />

business.<br />

IoD members are welcome to submit ideas to the journal, or articles for<br />

possible publication. Please email Kathryn Allix at: kathryn.allix@iod.com.


Big Picture<br />

Editor in Chief<br />

Graeme Leach, Chief Economist and Director <strong>of</strong> Policy at the IoD<br />

Policy Unit Editor<br />

Mike Harris, Head <strong>of</strong> Policy Development at the IoD<br />

Consultant Editor<br />

Tom Nash<br />

Sub Editor<br />

Ingrid Farmer<br />

Graphics and Design<br />

Alex Grant<br />

Production and Distribution<br />

Lisa Robertson, Kathryn Allix<br />

Cover illustration<br />

Ian Dodds<br />

CONTRIBUTORS<br />

Corin Taylor<br />

Senior Economic Adviser at the IoD<br />

Dan Lewis<br />

Chief Executive <strong>of</strong> Future Energy Strategies<br />

Graeme Leach<br />

Chief Economist and Director <strong>of</strong> Policy at the IoD<br />

Alexander Ehmann<br />

Head <strong>of</strong> Regulation and Employment at the IoD<br />

Richard Baron<br />

Head <strong>of</strong> Taxation at the IoD<br />

James Stanfield<br />

Director <strong>of</strong> Development at the E.G. West Centre at<br />

Newcastle University<br />

William Moore<br />

Economic Intern at the IoD<br />

© Copyright <strong>Institute</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Directors</strong>, December 2012. All rights reserved.<br />

Reproduction in whole or in part without written permission is strictly prohibited. Opinions expressed are<br />

those <strong>of</strong> the authors and do not necessarily reflect IoD policy. The IoD accepts no responsibility for the<br />

views expressed. Readers should consult their pr<strong>of</strong>essional advisers before acting on any issue raised.


4 Big Picture<br />

Contents<br />

WINTER 2012/13<br />

6<br />

20<br />

28<br />

COVER STORY<br />

All <strong>hail</strong> <strong>shale</strong><br />

Corin Taylor, Senior Economic Adviser<br />

at the IoD, and Dan Lewis, Chief<br />

Executive <strong>of</strong> Future Energy Strategies,<br />

set out the benefits <strong>of</strong> <strong>shale</strong><br />

development in the US and examine<br />

the enormous potential <strong>of</strong> Britain’s own<br />

<strong>shale</strong> gas resources. They argue that<br />

the Government should grasp the<br />

opportunity to develop what could be<br />

a vital part <strong>of</strong> this country’s future<br />

energy mix.<br />

Still going down?<br />

Graeme Leach, IoD Chief Economist<br />

and Director <strong>of</strong> Policy, looks at the<br />

vulnerability <strong>of</strong> the euro and whether<br />

recent interventions by the European<br />

Central Bank have changed the game.<br />

Industrial<br />

inaction:<br />

controlling the<br />

super unions<br />

Alexander Ehmann, Head <strong>of</strong> Regulation<br />

and Employment at the IoD, considers<br />

the rise <strong>of</strong> the ‘super unions’ and<br />

proposes a range <strong>of</strong> reforms to update<br />

the UK’s strike laws.


40<br />

50<br />

66<br />

76<br />

How to get rid <strong>of</strong><br />

corporation tax<br />

Richard Baron, Head <strong>of</strong> Taxation at the<br />

IoD, explains how we could improve<br />

the tax system by eliminating<br />

corporation tax.<br />

Flying into<br />

the future<br />

In comprehensive new research, Corin<br />

Taylor, Senior Economic Adviser at the<br />

IoD, analyses the constraints on the<br />

UK’s airport capacity and sets out a<br />

holistic long-term plan to address the<br />

country’s aviation challenges.<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>it in education<br />

– not a dirty word<br />

James Stanfield, Director <strong>of</strong><br />

Development at the E.G. West Centre<br />

at Newcastle University, examines the<br />

existing role played by for-pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

companies in the education sector, and<br />

questions the prejudice against<br />

extending their remit.<br />

Future cities –<br />

the survival <strong>of</strong><br />

the fastest<br />

William Moore, Economic Intern at the<br />

IoD, describes the future dynamics <strong>of</strong><br />

the world’s major cities.<br />

5


6 Big Picture


SNAPSHOT<br />

o The UK has not had many<br />

positive energy stories in<br />

recent years, but the<br />

discovery and exploitation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the country’s potentially<br />

huge <strong>shale</strong> gas reserves<br />

could prove to be just the<br />

boost the economy needs.<br />

o The UK has a major<br />

opportunity to develop a<br />

cheap and reliable<br />

domestic source <strong>of</strong> energy,<br />

creating jobs, reducing the<br />

need for gas imports and<br />

improving the environment<br />

by replacing coal in<br />

electricity generation.<br />

o Cheap gas-fired turbines<br />

powered by UK <strong>shale</strong><br />

resources could also prove<br />

to be the perfect<br />

complement to renewable<br />

generation, providing<br />

power when the wind isn’t<br />

blowing and the sun isn’t<br />

shining.<br />

o The UK faces a range <strong>of</strong><br />

energy issues, from falling<br />

North Sea production to<br />

declining coal and nuclear<br />

capacity. Shale gas<br />

development does not<br />

magically solve all the UK’s<br />

energy problems, but it can<br />

mitigate their impact.<br />

o The Government should be<br />

enthusiastic about<br />

developing what could be a<br />

vital part <strong>of</strong> the UK’s future<br />

energy mix.<br />

All <strong>hail</strong> <strong>shale</strong><br />

The UK could do with some good energy news. North Sea<br />

production is declining. Our mostly foreign-owned utilities<br />

are over-indebted, putting a major hurdle in the way <strong>of</strong> a<br />

new nuclear programme. Fuel poverty is a serious worry.<br />

The renewables programme is adding far more to industrial energy<br />

costs than comparable programmes in our competitor countries.<br />

And there is still a major question mark over carbon capture and<br />

storage, without which coal has little future.<br />

Gas will no doubt play a major role, not just as a bridging fuel or a<br />

back-up to wind, but in its own right, providing relatively clean,<br />

cheap and secure energy. Globally, we are poised to enter what the<br />

International Energy Agency (IEA) has described as a “golden age <strong>of</strong><br />

gas”. 1<br />

But that may come as little comfort to the UK, if it has to<br />

import the vast bulk <strong>of</strong> its supply.<br />

Fortunately, the UK has huge quantities <strong>of</strong> gas still to be tapped. And<br />

advances in <strong>shale</strong> extraction technology are bringing these resources<br />

closer by the day. Shale gas has the potential to make up for a good<br />

part <strong>of</strong> falling North Sea gas production, generating local jobs, keeping<br />

energy prices down, bringing in tax revenues, and cutting carbon and<br />

improving air quality by replacing coal in electricity generation.<br />

The UK has a massive opportunity, if the Government chooses to<br />

embrace it.<br />

THE US SHALE BOOM<br />

All <strong>hail</strong> <strong>shale</strong> 7<br />

Corin Taylor, Senior Economic Adviser at the IoD,<br />

and Dan Lewis, Chief Executive <strong>of</strong> Future Energy<br />

Strategies, set out the benefits <strong>of</strong> <strong>shale</strong><br />

development in the US and examine the enormous<br />

potential <strong>of</strong> Britain’s own <strong>shale</strong> gas resources.<br />

The UK is not the US, but there can be no understanding <strong>of</strong> this<br />

country’s <strong>shale</strong> gas opportunity without a thorough grasp <strong>of</strong> how<br />

unconventional production has transformed America.<br />

Production<br />

Since its 2005 low, US natural gas production has increased by<br />

28%. Shale gas production has accounted for the bulk <strong>of</strong> this rise,<br />

increasing from 0.39 trillion cubic feet (tcf) in 2000 to around 5<br />

tcf in 2010, accounting for 23% <strong>of</strong> all US natural gas production.<br />

By 2035, <strong>shale</strong> gas is expected to account for 49% <strong>of</strong> US natural<br />

gas production.<br />

1 International Energy Agency, Golden Rules for a Golden Age <strong>of</strong> Gas, 2012.


8 Big Picture<br />

CHART 1<br />

US natural gas production 1990-2035<br />

Trillion cubic feet<br />

30<br />

25<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

5<br />

0<br />

History 2010 Projections<br />

Source: US Energy Information Administration, Annual Energy Outlook 2012: Early Release Overview.<br />

CHART 2<br />

1990<br />

1995<br />

Alaska<br />

2%<br />

2000<br />

2005<br />

23%<br />

26%<br />

9%<br />

9%<br />

10%<br />

21%<br />

2010<br />

Henry Hub Gulf Coast natural gas spot price<br />

$ per million British Thermal Units<br />

14<br />

12<br />

10<br />

8<br />

6<br />

4<br />

2<br />

0<br />

Shale gas<br />

Tight gas<br />

Non-associated <strong>of</strong>fshore<br />

Coalbed methane<br />

Associated with oil<br />

Non-associated onshore<br />

2015<br />

2020<br />

49%<br />

21%<br />

7%<br />

1%<br />

7%<br />

7%<br />

9%<br />

Prices<br />

We need not be resigned to constantly rising power prices. US natural<br />

gas prices are now at a 10-year low, while peak wholesale electricity<br />

prices fell by 24-39% in the first six months <strong>of</strong> 2012. Shale gas is not<br />

the only reason for these falls, but it certainly helps.<br />

Source: US Energy Information Administration, ‘Natural gas spot and futures prices’.<br />

2025<br />

2030<br />

2035<br />

Jan 08<br />

Apr 08<br />

Jul 08<br />

Oct 08<br />

Jan 09<br />

Apr 09<br />

Jul 09<br />

Oct 09<br />

Jan 10<br />

Apr 10<br />

Jul 10<br />

Oct 10<br />

Jan 11<br />

Apr 11<br />

Jul 11<br />

Oct 11<br />

Jan 12<br />

Apr 12


“US natural gas prices<br />

are at a 10-year low,<br />

while peak wholesale<br />

electricity prices fell by<br />

24-39% in the first six<br />

months <strong>of</strong> 2012.”<br />

All <strong>hail</strong> <strong>shale</strong> 9<br />

US natural gas prices are now de-indexed from oil prices. In addition<br />

to the rapid development <strong>of</strong> <strong>shale</strong> gas, a crucial part <strong>of</strong> this has been a<br />

highly liquid trading hub – Henry Hub – which is located at the<br />

crossover point <strong>of</strong> many major pipelines governing gas markets on the<br />

East Coast <strong>of</strong> America. When oil prices began to increase again in<br />

2009, natural gas prices continued to fall. All over the US, oil-linked<br />

gas contracts have been torn up.<br />

Industry and exports<br />

US industry now benefits from some <strong>of</strong> the lowest natural gas prices in<br />

the world, leading to production moving back to the US, especially in<br />

the chemical industry. In a recent report, Citigroup projected that, by<br />

2020, up to 3.6 million new jobs could be created in the energy<br />

sector and the wider economy from the <strong>shale</strong> energy boom, boosting<br />

GDP by 2.0-3.3%. 2<br />

According to PwC, <strong>shale</strong> gas could save US manufacturers alone up to<br />

$11.6bn a year in natural gas costs by 2020, while one million new<br />

manufacturing jobs could be created by 2025. 3<br />

LNG import terminals, constructed before the <strong>shale</strong> gas boom, are<br />

now being refitted for export. The US Energy Information<br />

Administration expects the country to become a net exporter <strong>of</strong> LNG<br />

by 2016 and a net exporter <strong>of</strong> natural gas overall by 2021. 4<br />

Environment<br />

According to the International Energy Agency, US CO 2 emissions have<br />

fallen by 450 million tonnes over the last five years, more than any<br />

other country. There are several reasons for this, including the<br />

recession, more efficient technology, increasing renewable generation,<br />

and, importantly, the displacement <strong>of</strong> coal by gas for electricity<br />

generation.<br />

Shale oil potential<br />

US unconventional production is not limited to <strong>shale</strong> gas. According<br />

to Citigroup, <strong>shale</strong> oil production could increase more than four-fold<br />

by 2020, from 0.7 million to 3 million barrels a day. Conventional<br />

deep water production is also forecast to increase rapidly, while overall<br />

US oil production could increase from 5.8 million barrels a day in<br />

2011 to 10.2 million by 2020, surpassing its peak in the 1970s.<br />

To say that this would be a massive change would be an<br />

understatement. It would effectively re-localise oil market pricing and<br />

signal the end <strong>of</strong> OPEC’s ability to keep oil prices high. We have<br />

already seen this start to happen with the growing difference between<br />

WTI (West Texas Intermediate) and Brent Crude oil prices – this is<br />

perhaps not dissimilar to the de-indexation <strong>of</strong> Henry Hub gas prices<br />

from the oil price.<br />

2 Citi Global Perspectives & Solutions, Energy 2020: North America, the New Middle East? March 2012.<br />

3 PricewaterhouseCoopers, Shale Gas: A renaissance in US manufacturing, December 2011.<br />

4 US Energy Information Administration, Annual Energy Outlook 2012: Early Release Overview, p. 2.


10 Big Picture<br />

TABLE 1<br />

Trillion cubic<br />

feet<br />

Eastern Europe/<br />

Eurasia<br />

Middle East<br />

Asia/Pacific<br />

OECD Americas<br />

Africa<br />

Latin America<br />

OECD Europe<br />

World<br />

“The IEA estimates<br />

that <strong>shale</strong> reserves<br />

alone are sufficient<br />

for 60 years <strong>of</strong><br />

global gas<br />

production.”<br />

Total<br />

reserves<br />

6,145<br />

4,838<br />

4,520<br />

4,308<br />

2,613<br />

2,507<br />

1,978<br />

26,557<br />

A ‘GOLDEN AGE’ OF GAS<br />

But it is not just the US. Shale and other unconventional gas<br />

resources have enormous global potential.<br />

Reserves<br />

The International Energy Agency estimates technically-recoverable gas<br />

reserves at 27,000 tcf, including 12,000 tcf <strong>of</strong> unconventional reserves,<br />

<strong>of</strong> which <strong>shale</strong> accounts for 7,000 tcf. Shale reserves alone are sufficient<br />

to account for 60 years <strong>of</strong> total global natural gas production. 5<br />

These reserves are widely distributed, with almost every region <strong>of</strong> the<br />

world, apart from the Middle East, possessing large <strong>shale</strong> gas deposits.<br />

Remaining technically-recoverable natural gas resources at end-2011<br />

Of which<br />

conventional<br />

reserves<br />

4,626<br />

4,414<br />

1,236<br />

1,589<br />

1,307<br />

812<br />

848<br />

14,868<br />

Of which<br />

unconventional<br />

reserves<br />

1,519<br />

424<br />

3,284<br />

2,719<br />

1,307<br />

1,695<br />

1,130<br />

11,689<br />

Unconventional Unconventional<br />

<strong>of</strong> which <strong>shale</strong> <strong>of</strong> which tight<br />

gas<br />

gas<br />

424<br />

141<br />

2,013<br />

1,978<br />

1,059<br />

1,165<br />

565<br />

7,346<br />

Production<br />

There is <strong>of</strong> course a difference between technically-recoverable<br />

reserves and those that are economic to recover – and the latter will<br />

always be smaller than the former. But production forecasts are<br />

similarly impressive.<br />

According to the International Energy Agency, provided <strong>shale</strong> gas is<br />

developed at scale outside <strong>of</strong> the US, world natural gas production<br />

could rise by more than 50% by 2035, with unconventional<br />

production accounting for around a third <strong>of</strong> the total. In this scenario,<br />

gas accounts for 34%, and renewables 31%, <strong>of</strong> global energy demand<br />

growth. BP’s forecasts are similar. 6<br />

The basic story, then, is quite straightforward. There are large global<br />

reserves <strong>of</strong> unconventional natural gas; unconventional production is<br />

likely to account for an increasing share <strong>of</strong> global gas production; and<br />

natural gas will become an increasingly important energy source, as<br />

demand for coal and oil starts to flatten out. Gas and renewables are<br />

likely to be the biggest energy growth stories over the next few decades.<br />

353<br />

283<br />

706<br />

424<br />

247<br />

530<br />

106<br />

2,684<br />

Unconventional<br />

<strong>of</strong> which coalbed<br />

methane<br />

706<br />

0<br />

565<br />

318<br />

0<br />

0<br />

71<br />

1,660<br />

Source: International Energy Agency, Golden Rules for a Golden Age <strong>of</strong> Gas, 2012, Table 2.1 (converted to trillion cubic feet).<br />

5 International Energy Agency, Golden Rules for a Golden Age <strong>of</strong> Gas, 2012, Tables 2.1 and 2.6 (converted to<br />

trillion cubic feet).<br />

6 BP, Energy Outlook 2030, January 2012.


“The basic story is<br />

straightforward. Gas<br />

and renewables will be<br />

the biggest energy<br />

growth stories in the<br />

next few decades.”<br />

BOX 1<br />

Estimates <strong>of</strong> the UK’s <strong>shale</strong> gas reserves<br />

THE UK’S POTENTIAL<br />

All <strong>hail</strong> <strong>shale</strong> 11<br />

The UK may not experience a US-style <strong>shale</strong> boom, but our <strong>shale</strong><br />

resources have enormous development potential. UK <strong>shale</strong> gas could<br />

help to support a cleaner, cheaper and more secure energy system.<br />

LNG imports from the US – not viable<br />

The first part <strong>of</strong> this article described the immense benefits that <strong>shale</strong><br />

gas has brought to the US and the future export potential. Given that<br />

UK gas currently costs around $8-9 per million British Thermal Units<br />

(MMBTU), compared to US gas costing $2-3 per MMBTU, it might be<br />

tempting to believe that the UK can import large quantities <strong>of</strong> cheap<br />

US gas in the years ahead. Unfortunately, at current production,<br />

liquefaction and shipping costs, it doesn’t look likely:<br />

o Firstly, Pacific Basin gas prices are far higher than those in the<br />

UK, so the most pr<strong>of</strong>itable export route will always be to Asia<br />

rather than Western Europe.<br />

o Secondly, and more importantly, some energy analysts forecast a<br />

return from the current $3 Henry Hub gas price to $5 in the near<br />

future. With the costs <strong>of</strong> export currently around $4 per MMBTU,<br />

exporting gas to the UK would actually be a loss-making<br />

enterprise, unless UK gas prices increased substantially.<br />

This view was confirmed in a recent Deutsche Bank report, which<br />

forecast that, once transportation costs were taken into account, US<br />

LNG would be no cheaper than the UK’s own National Balancing<br />

Point (NBP) gas price. 7<br />

The UK is therefore unlikely to be importing<br />

US gas at scale anytime soon. As a country, we have to look to our<br />

own resources.<br />

UK <strong>shale</strong> resources<br />

Estimates <strong>of</strong> UK <strong>shale</strong> resources are being constantly updated, as the<br />

UK is still in the exploration stage, but the prospects look very<br />

promising indeed, as Box 1 illustrates.<br />

o In 2010, the British Geological Survey (BGS) estimated the UK’s onshore <strong>shale</strong> reserves at 5.3 trillion<br />

cubic feet. At the time <strong>of</strong> writing, the BGS was set to revise its onshore data substantially upwards,<br />

possibly to as high as 200 tcf.<br />

o The exploration companies themselves have far higher estimates from their onshore fields: Cuadrilla<br />

– 200 tcf; Dart Energy – 76 tcf; Eden Energy – 12.8 tcf; IGas – 4.6 tcf. This adds up to nearly 300 tcf<br />

in total.<br />

o Offshore reserves could be far higher still. The BGS has said that they could be 5-10 times larger<br />

than onshore reserves – potentially up to 1,000 tcf. Offshore reserves are, however, far harder to<br />

extract.<br />

o By comparison, UK gas consumption runs at around 3 tcf a year.<br />

7 “Price <strong>of</strong> US LNG at parity with UK NBP prices from 2016 – Deutsche Bank”, Gas to Power Journal, Friday 3<br />

August 2012.


12 Big Picture<br />

“The UK’s <strong>shale</strong><br />

resources have<br />

enormous potential<br />

and could support a<br />

cleaner, cheaper and<br />

more secure energy<br />

system.”<br />

CHART 3<br />

Recovery rates, though, do vary by location and geology. In the US,<br />

<strong>shale</strong> gas recovery rates average 18%. 8<br />

There may be reasons to<br />

expect recovery rates in the UK to be lower:<br />

o UK <strong>shale</strong> gas may or may not be harder to recover, given the<br />

different geological conditions and greater population density.<br />

o UK planning laws are more stringent.<br />

o In the UK, unlike in the US, mineral ownership rights belong to<br />

the Crown Estate and not the landowner, meaning that the<br />

landowner may have less incentive to allow <strong>shale</strong> drilling.<br />

Nevertheless, technological improvements are increasing the proportion<br />

<strong>of</strong> reserves that are economic to recover. And UK reserves may be <strong>of</strong><br />

good quality. According to Cuadrilla, the Bowland Shale is around 10<br />

times thicker than leading US <strong>shale</strong> gas plays – although it is still early<br />

days, recovery in the UK could potentially be quite rapid.<br />

The UK’s energy squeeze<br />

The UK is experiencing and will experience a number <strong>of</strong> problems<br />

with its energy supply:<br />

1. Gas production from the UK Continental Shelf has declined<br />

rapidly over the last decade, from 103 to 41 million tonnes <strong>of</strong><br />

oil equivalent per annum. By 2030, production is expected to<br />

fall to just 18 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> oil equivalent. The number <strong>of</strong><br />

people employed directly and indirectly by the oil and gas<br />

industry, currently 440,000, will therefore fall.<br />

2. Gas imports are rising rapidly. In 2000, the UK produced 13%<br />

more gas than it consumed, which it exported. In 2011, it<br />

produced 49% less than it consumed, which it imported. By 2030,<br />

imports are projected to increase to 74% <strong>of</strong> consumption.<br />

Declining North Sea gas production and gas imports as a percentage <strong>of</strong> demand<br />

Million tonnes <strong>of</strong> oil equivalent<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

Net UKCS production<br />

Projected net UKCS production<br />

(Left-hand scale)<br />

8 Centre for Global Energy Studies, July 2010.<br />

2000<br />

2002<br />

2004<br />

2006<br />

2008<br />

2010<br />

2012<br />

2014<br />

2016<br />

2018<br />

2020<br />

2022<br />

2024<br />

2026<br />

2028<br />

2030<br />

Gas import dependency<br />

Projected gas import dependency<br />

(Right-hand scale)<br />

Source: Department <strong>of</strong> Energy and Climate Change, UKCS Oil and Gas Production Projections, March 2012.<br />

80%<br />

70%<br />

60%<br />

50%<br />

40%<br />

30%<br />

20%<br />

10%<br />

0%<br />

-10%<br />

-20%<br />

Net gas imports as % <strong>of</strong> net gas demand


“Carried out carefully<br />

and under thorough<br />

regulation, fracking is<br />

no more dangerous<br />

than conventional<br />

extraction.”<br />

3. The UK’s energy and climate policies are adding more to<br />

industrial electricity prices than comparable programmes in<br />

competitor countries, putting UK industry at a disadvantage<br />

and making a rebalancing <strong>of</strong> the economy more difficult. By<br />

2020, US policies are projected to add nothing to industrial<br />

electricity prices, Chinese policies to add £10 per megawatt<br />

hour (MWh), German policies to add £17 per MWh and British<br />

policies to add £28 per MWh, <strong>of</strong> which £20 will be accounted<br />

for by the costs <strong>of</strong> the renewables programme.<br />

4. The proportion <strong>of</strong> households in fuel poverty has risen from<br />

6% in 2003 to 16% in 2010. So far, most <strong>of</strong> the rise has been<br />

due to the impact <strong>of</strong> higher gas prices, but the latest Department<br />

<strong>of</strong> Energy and Climate Change projections show that<br />

renewables subsidies and other climate and energy policies are<br />

set to add 7% to domestic gas prices and 27% to domestic<br />

electricity prices by 2020. Improved energy efficiency may<br />

reduce the bill impact, but fuel poverty could rise still further.<br />

5. By 2020, the UK is set to lose around 20GW <strong>of</strong> coal and<br />

nuclear generation, around a fifth <strong>of</strong> total electricity<br />

generating capacity. A new nuclear programme is vital, but will<br />

not achieve scale until sometime after 2020, while carbon<br />

capture and storage (CCS), which is vital for coal generation to<br />

continue, is not yet proven commercially.<br />

An economic boost<br />

Developing UK <strong>shale</strong> does not solve all <strong>of</strong> these energy problems on<br />

its own, but it could make a major contribution to mitigating their<br />

impact, providing a major economic boost.<br />

In the US, where <strong>shale</strong> gas recovery rates average 18%, <strong>shale</strong> gas<br />

production increased from virtually zero to sufficient to meet over a<br />

fifth (22%) <strong>of</strong> US natural gas consumption in only a decade. If, over<br />

the next 10 years, the UK is roughly half as successful on both<br />

measures as the US has been over the last 10 years, it would mean<br />

that <strong>shale</strong> gas could account for around 10% <strong>of</strong> 2011 UK gas<br />

consumption, and that around 10% <strong>of</strong> the UK’s onshore <strong>shale</strong> reserves<br />

prove to be economic to recover.<br />

If, in this way, the UK is half as successful at developing <strong>shale</strong> gas as<br />

the US, the benefits could be enormous, as Box 2 sets out.<br />

THE ENVIRONMENT<br />

It is impossible to talk about <strong>shale</strong> gas without discussing the<br />

environmental concerns. Using gas in place <strong>of</strong> coal for electricity, and<br />

in place <strong>of</strong> petrol and diesel for road transport, would lead to big<br />

improvements in air quality and a reduction in CO 2 emissions. The<br />

process <strong>of</strong> extracting <strong>shale</strong> gas, however, has been heavily criticised on<br />

environmental grounds. But if carried out carefully and under<br />

thorough regulation, hydraulic fracturing (‘fracking’) is no more<br />

dangerous than conventional hydrocarbon extraction.<br />

Air quality and carbon emissions<br />

In 2011, the UK used 42 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> coal in electricity<br />

All <strong>hail</strong> <strong>shale</strong> 13


14 Big Picture<br />

BOX 2<br />

Estimating the economic benefits <strong>of</strong> <strong>shale</strong> for the UK<br />

The following are very indicative calculations, designed to provide an appreciation <strong>of</strong> the big picture<br />

surrounding UK <strong>shale</strong>:<br />

o In 2011, the UK consumed 2.9 tcf <strong>of</strong> gas. 10% <strong>of</strong> 2011 UK gas demand is therefore 0.29 tcf. If 10%<br />

<strong>of</strong> the 300 tcf <strong>of</strong> onshore reserves estimated by the exploration companies were economic to<br />

recover, then 30 tcf would be sufficient to meet 10% <strong>of</strong> current UK gas demand for 103 years.<br />

o 10% <strong>of</strong> 2011 UK gas demand is equal to 8 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> oil equivalent, 8% <strong>of</strong> total UK oil and gas<br />

production in 2011. The UK oil and gas industry provides direct and indirect employment for 440,000<br />

people. Assuming that jobs are directly proportional to production, then an extra 8% <strong>of</strong> 2011<br />

production would generate 35,000 extra jobs, helping to <strong>of</strong>fset job losses from a decline in<br />

conventional oil and gas production in the UK.<br />

o Between 2011 and 2022, conventional UK gas production is forecast to decline by 13 million tonnes<br />

<strong>of</strong> oil equivalent. If <strong>shale</strong> production rose to 8 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> oil equivalent, it would <strong>of</strong>fset 60% <strong>of</strong><br />

the projected fall in conventional production.<br />

o 8 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> oil equivalent also represents 20% <strong>of</strong> projected UK gas imports in 2022. This<br />

would be sufficient to keep gas imports at the 2011 level <strong>of</strong> 49% <strong>of</strong> demand, rather than imports<br />

rising to a projected 59% <strong>of</strong> demand.<br />

generation, 9<br />

emitting around 90 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> CO2. 10<br />

Were this to<br />

be replaced with gas, which emits around half as much carbon, the<br />

UK could save around 45 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> CO2, around 8% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

2011 total. Although UK <strong>shale</strong> is unlikely to be sufficient to replace all<br />

coal-fired generation, it could make a major contribution to<br />

decarbonisation in its own right, as well as supporting the further<br />

development <strong>of</strong> renewables.<br />

According to DECC’s projections, around 25GW <strong>of</strong> renewable<br />

generation will be added to the grid by 2020, much <strong>of</strong> which will be<br />

in the form <strong>of</strong> intermittent sources such as wind and solar. UK <strong>shale</strong><br />

gas can support this development, ensuring that the lights stay on<br />

when the wind isn’t blowing and the sun isn’t shining.<br />

Natural gas emits far fewer particulates and other pollutants than coal<br />

and diesel. Using natural gas in place <strong>of</strong> coal for electricity generation<br />

and switching over buses and other vehicles to natural gas could<br />

reduce the 29,000 annual deaths from poor air quality in the UK. 11<br />

Hydraulic fracturing<br />

There are several environmental issues associated with hydraulic<br />

fracturing, detailed in Table 2. They are not to be taken lightly, but at<br />

the same time must be put into perspective.<br />

Good practice can significantly reduce many <strong>of</strong> these environmental<br />

risks. Multiple casing <strong>of</strong> wells ensures that fracking fluid cannot enter<br />

the water table, while proper site construction and disposal <strong>of</strong> fracking<br />

fluid will ensure that there are no surface leaks. Real-time seismic<br />

monitoring minimises earthquake risks.<br />

9 Department <strong>of</strong> Energy and Climate Change, Digest <strong>of</strong> UK Energy Statistics (DUKES), Annual Tables, Table 2.7,<br />

‘Supply and consumption <strong>of</strong> coal’.<br />

10 Department <strong>of</strong> Energy and Climate Change, 2011 UK Greenhouse Gas Emissions, Provisional Figures, March<br />

2012, Figure 3.<br />

11 Simon Moore and Guy Newey, The forgotten crisis <strong>of</strong> Britain’s poor air quality, Policy Exchange, July 2012.


BOX 3<br />

What is fracking?<br />

In the early 1980s, George Phydias Mitchell, a Texan born to Greek parents, came up with the radical idea <strong>of</strong><br />

drilling much deeper into the gas-bearing <strong>shale</strong> rock to extract natural gas. After nearly 20 years <strong>of</strong><br />

experimentation, his company finally found the right formula for the economic exploitation <strong>of</strong> tight <strong>shale</strong> gas.<br />

Hydraulic fracturing, or ‘fracking’, literally breaks open the rock along fractures and releases the trapped<br />

gas. This is done by firing a cheap combination <strong>of</strong> high pressure water, sand as a propping agent to<br />

open up the fractures, and some chemicals. These follow after the vertical well has been drilled, which<br />

is encased with steel and concrete to prevent the well’s collapse and the escape <strong>of</strong> gas or fracking fluid.<br />

A more recent discovery has been to drill horizontally outwards from the vertical well as far as 5,000<br />

feet. Hydraulic fracturing horizontally requires much more water but it also means that one drill pad can<br />

cover a much larger area and extract much more gas. This is known as multi wellpad drilling.<br />

The fracking itself only lasts a few weeks but the well will keep producing gas for 30-40 years as it<br />

would typically be connected to the gas network.<br />

TABLE 2<br />

Environmental risks <strong>of</strong> hydraulic fracturing<br />

RISK<br />

Water<br />

Methane migrating to the water<br />

table as a result <strong>of</strong> drilling<br />

Chemicals used in the fracking fluid<br />

polluting ground and surface water<br />

Large quantities <strong>of</strong> water<br />

Earthquakes<br />

Earthquakes caused by the fracking<br />

process<br />

Fugitive emissions<br />

Leaks from the <strong>shale</strong> wells <strong>of</strong><br />

methane or other pollutants<br />

PERSPECTIVE<br />

Methane can sometimes migrate in any case, although any<br />

migration caused by fracking needs to be taken seriously.<br />

The chemicals used in fracking fluid are generally less than 0.5%<br />

<strong>of</strong> the total, and are used in all walks <strong>of</strong> life. For example, Sodium<br />

Chloride is salt, Polyacrylamide is used for water treatment and in<br />

cosmetics, Borate salts are found in laundry detergent, Citric Acid<br />

is used in food additives and Sodium/Potassium Carbonate is<br />

found in ordinary detergents. Disposing <strong>of</strong> chemicals safely is not<br />

a unique problem for <strong>shale</strong> gas drilling.<br />

Large quantities <strong>of</strong> water are, <strong>of</strong> course, used in many industrial<br />

and leisure activities.<br />

In 2011, two earthquakes were caused by the activities <strong>of</strong> Cuadrilla,<br />

one measuring 1.5 and the other measuring 2.3 on the Richter<br />

scale. For comparison, the British Geological Survey publishes a<br />

record <strong>of</strong> earthquakes around the British Isles in the last 50 days.<br />

Based on a search conducted on 15 August 2012, in the previous 50<br />

days there were five earthquakes measuring more than 1.5, <strong>of</strong><br />

which two measured 2.3 and one 2.7. 12<br />

Coal mining has also<br />

caused earthquakes <strong>of</strong> a similar magnitude for a long time. It<br />

should also be noted that earthquake magnitudes are exponential,<br />

not linear. According to the British Geological Survey, an earthquake<br />

below 3.0 is generally not even felt, let alone the cause <strong>of</strong> damage.<br />

Not a problem uniquely confined to <strong>shale</strong> gas wells, but to coal<br />

mining as well.<br />

12 British Geological Survey, ‘Earthquakes around the British Isles in the last 50 days; Last updated:<br />

13.40, Wednesday August 15, 2012’.<br />

All <strong>hail</strong> <strong>shale</strong> 15


16 Big Picture<br />

TABLE 3<br />

Environmental controls in England and Wales<br />

RISK<br />

Groundwater pollution<br />

Surface spills<br />

Disposal <strong>of</strong> used fracking fluid<br />

Over-abstraction <strong>of</strong> water<br />

Fugitive methane emissions<br />

“Earthquakes caused<br />

by hydraulic fracturing<br />

are no larger than<br />

those that have been<br />

caused by coal mining<br />

for years.”<br />

The UK has numerous regulatory bodies (including the Department <strong>of</strong><br />

Energy and Climate Change, the Environment Agency and the Health<br />

and Safety Executive) and regulations to monitor and oversee the<br />

drilling process, as outlined in Table 3.<br />

CONTROLS<br />

Water Framework Directive and Groundwater Daughter Directive<br />

through the Water Resources Act and Environmental Permitting<br />

Regulations (EPR). These regulate discharges to groundwater<br />

and require disclosure <strong>of</strong> chemicals.<br />

Planning regime for site construction standards. The EPR<br />

regulate discharges to surface water and groundwater.<br />

Mining Waste Directive through the EPR. A waste management<br />

plan must be approved by the Environment Agency. Euratom<br />

Treaty applies if there are naturally occurring radioactive<br />

materials, via the EPR.<br />

Abstraction licensing under the Water Resources Act.<br />

Borehole regulations (Health and Safety Executive) to protect<br />

human health. Conditions under Petroleum Licences (DECC) for<br />

flaring and venting. Mining Waste Directive may apply.<br />

Source: Tony Grayling, the Environment Agency’s Head <strong>of</strong> Climate Change and Communities, Managing the environmental<br />

risks <strong>of</strong> <strong>shale</strong> gas extraction, Presentation to the UKERC Annual Assembly, University <strong>of</strong> Warwick, 20 June 2012.<br />

Safety<br />

Several scientific reports on safety in the UK have also been published,<br />

including by the Energy and Climate Change Select Committee,<br />

DECC, and the Royal Society and Royal Academy <strong>of</strong> Engineering (see<br />

Box 4 for more details). The findings <strong>of</strong> these reports include:<br />

o Carried out properly and under strict regulation, hydraulic<br />

fracturing is safe.<br />

o Problems are generally due to poor standards, rather than the<br />

hydraulic fracturing process itself.<br />

o Environmental issues are generally little different from those <strong>of</strong><br />

conventional hydrocarbon extraction.<br />

o Earthquakes caused by hydraulic fracturing are no larger than<br />

those that have been caused by coal mining for years.<br />

In the US, over 20,000 <strong>shale</strong> wells have been drilled. The US Environmental<br />

Protection Agency is currently undertaking a major study on the safety <strong>of</strong><br />

hydraulic fracturing. Although there have been problems at a small<br />

number <strong>of</strong> wells, these are generally due to poor practice, rather than the<br />

nature <strong>of</strong> the process itself. The UK, <strong>of</strong> course, has the opportunity to learn<br />

from mistakes made in the US.<br />

The International Energy Agency has also set out a number <strong>of</strong> ‘golden<br />

rules’ for unconventional gas exploration to address environmental<br />

concerns. Following these golden rules would add at least 7% to<br />

costs, but would make significant <strong>shale</strong> gas development outside <strong>of</strong><br />

North America far more acceptable. 13<br />

13 International Energy Agency, Golden Rules for a Golden Age <strong>of</strong> Gas, 2012.


Looking at the views <strong>of</strong> insurers is crucial to understanding the<br />

environmental risks <strong>of</strong> hydraulic fracturing, as their conclusions will<br />

affect their own pr<strong>of</strong>its. A recent report from the major insurance<br />

brokerage Willis found that, if best practice is followed, there is no<br />

reason for insurers to deny cover. The report concluded:<br />

“While hydraulic fracking operations will continue to pose a measure <strong>of</strong><br />

pollution and contamination risk – just like the upstream oil and gas<br />

industry or any other industrial process in general – the extent <strong>of</strong> the<br />

problem has, in some quarters <strong>of</strong> the media at least, perhaps been blown<br />

somewhat out <strong>of</strong> proportion...<br />

“Our study has shown that cover is much more likely to be provided to<br />

those buyers who can demonstrate that they have completely bought into<br />

the highest standards <strong>of</strong> the industry. Indeed, the contrast between<br />

contractors who do indeed adhere to these standards and those who do<br />

not is already very pronounced.” 14<br />

Shale gas and the technique used to extract it attract strong views on<br />

either side <strong>of</strong> the debate. An examination <strong>of</strong> the evidence base<br />

indicates that the environmental risks <strong>of</strong> hydraulic fracturing should be<br />

placed alongside those <strong>of</strong> conventional hydrocarbon extraction. In<br />

other words, the risks <strong>of</strong> fracking should not be put in a class <strong>of</strong> their<br />

own. Should hydraulic fracturing be no more risky than conventional<br />

14 Willis, All Fracked Up? Just how concerned should energy insurers be about hydraulic fracturing? Energy<br />

Market Review, April 2012, p. 28.<br />

All <strong>hail</strong> <strong>shale</strong> 17<br />

A drilling rig in the Tioga State Forest, Pennsylvania


18 Big Picture<br />

BOX 4<br />

Conclusions <strong>of</strong> UK scientific reports on the safety <strong>of</strong> hydraulic fracturing<br />

Energy and Climate Change Committee, May 2011:<br />

“There is no evidence that the hydraulic fracturing process poses any risk to underground water aquifers<br />

provided that the well-casing is intact before the process commences. Rather, the risks <strong>of</strong> water<br />

contamination are due to issues <strong>of</strong> well integrity, and are no different to concerns encountered during the<br />

extraction <strong>of</strong> oil and gas from conventional reservoirs. However, the large volumes <strong>of</strong> water required for<br />

<strong>shale</strong> gas could challenge resources in regions already experiencing water stress.” 15<br />

Report commissioned by DECC on the Cuadrilla earthquakes, April 2012:<br />

“Based on the induced seismicity analysis done by Cuadrilla and ourselves, together with the agreement to<br />

use more sensitive fracture monitoring equipment and a DECC agreed induced seismic protocol for future<br />

operations, the authors <strong>of</strong> this report see no reason why Cuadrilla Resources Ltd. should not be allowed to<br />

proceed with their <strong>shale</strong> gas exploration activities and recommend cautious continuation <strong>of</strong> hydraulic<br />

fracture operations at the Preese Hall site. In respect <strong>of</strong> future <strong>shale</strong> gas operations elsewhere in the UK, we<br />

recommend that seismic hazards should be assessed prior to proceeding with these operations.” 16<br />

Royal Society and Royal Academy <strong>of</strong> Engineering, June 2012:<br />

“Natural seismicity in the UK is low by world standards. On average, the UK experiences seismicity <strong>of</strong><br />

magnitude 5 ML (felt by everyone nearby) every twenty years, and <strong>of</strong> magnitude 4 ML (felt by many people)<br />

every three to four years. The UK has lived with seismicity induced by coal mining activities or the<br />

settlement <strong>of</strong> abandoned mines for a long time. British Geological Survey records indicate that coal miningrelated<br />

seismicity is generally <strong>of</strong> smaller magnitude than natural seismicity and no larger than 4 ML.<br />

Seismicity induced by hydraulic fracturing is likely to be <strong>of</strong> even smaller magnitude. There is an emerging<br />

consensus that the magnitude <strong>of</strong> seismicity induced by hydraulic fracturing would be no greater than 3 ML<br />

(felt by few people and resulting in negligible, if any, surface impacts. Recent seismicity induced by<br />

hydraulic fracturing in the UK was <strong>of</strong> magnitude 2.3 ML and 1.5 ML (unlikely to be felt by anyone).” 17<br />

hydrocarbon extraction, it follows that there can be net benefits to<br />

the environment from using unconventional gas in place <strong>of</strong> coal in<br />

electricity generation and oil in road transport.<br />

CONCLUSIONS<br />

Shale gas development does not magically solve all the UK’s energy<br />

issues. North Sea production will still fall, the renewables programme<br />

will still increase energy prices for industry, and coal and nuclear will<br />

still decline in capacity. But what <strong>shale</strong> gas development can do is<br />

mitigate the impact <strong>of</strong> these trends, providing a big economic boost<br />

in the process:<br />

o Shale gas development can counter falling North Sea production,<br />

halting the increase in gas imports.<br />

o UK <strong>shale</strong> gas can <strong>of</strong>fer a cheap and reliable energy source for<br />

industry, potentially reducing the number <strong>of</strong> job losses.<br />

o Shale gas can also help to reduce price rises for consumers,<br />

reducing the number <strong>of</strong> people in fuel poverty.<br />

15 House <strong>of</strong> Commons Energy and Climate Change Committee, Shale Gas: Fifth Report <strong>of</strong> Session 2010-12,<br />

May 2011.<br />

16 Dr Christopher Green, Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Peter Styles and Dr Brian Baptie, Preese Hall Shale Gas Fracturing: Review<br />

and Recommendations for Induced Seismic Mitigation, April 2012.<br />

17 The Royal Society and the Royal Academy <strong>of</strong> Engineering, Shale gas extraction in the UK: A review <strong>of</strong><br />

hydraulic fracturing, June 2012.


BOX 5<br />

The views <strong>of</strong> IoD members<br />

All <strong>hail</strong> <strong>shale</strong> 19<br />

o Expanding renewables creates jobs directly, and so can<br />

developing <strong>shale</strong> gas, especially in less affluent parts <strong>of</strong> the country.<br />

o With coal and nuclear set to decline in importance, at least<br />

before new nuclear power stations come on stream, new gas<br />

plants powered by UK <strong>shale</strong> can help to fill the electricity<br />

generation gap, as well as acting as a vital back-up to wind and<br />

other renewables.<br />

A mix <strong>of</strong> power sources is vital, and domestic <strong>shale</strong> gas is unlikely to<br />

account for a majority <strong>of</strong> the UK’s electricity generation, or even <strong>of</strong> its gas<br />

usage. But it could and should play an important role. In the US, <strong>shale</strong> gas<br />

accounts for around a quarter <strong>of</strong> overall gas production, and yet that has<br />

been sufficient to revolutionise the gas market, cutting costs for industry<br />

and replacing coal in electricity generation. The same economic and<br />

environmental benefits could be realised in the UK, if we allow <strong>shale</strong><br />

development to happen.<br />

Our own research into the views <strong>of</strong> IoD members found them to favour careful, well-regulated <strong>shale</strong> gas<br />

development in the UK. To inform the IoD’s research in this area, 1,095 IoD members were surveyed in a<br />

Policy Voice poll in April 2012. Their views were not unanimous, but were positive overall. 58% thought<br />

that extensive development <strong>of</strong> the UK’s <strong>shale</strong> reserves would have a positive impact on British<br />

businesses. Just over a third (36%) thought that the risks <strong>of</strong> hydraulic fracturing were significant. By<br />

comparison, 17% thought that the risks were insignificant and 27% that they were neither significant<br />

nor insignificant (19% did not know). Almost half (48%) agreed that the benefits outweighed the risks,<br />

compared to 18% who thought that the risks outweighed the benefits.


20 Big Picture


SNAPSHOT<br />

o The eurozone remains highly<br />

vulnerable to a break-up<br />

between the core and<br />

peripheral economies. The<br />

centrifugal forces pulling the<br />

euro apart remain stronger<br />

than the centripetal forces<br />

holding it together.<br />

o The survival <strong>of</strong> the euro in its<br />

current form depends on<br />

huge purchases <strong>of</strong> peripheral<br />

country bonds by the ECB –<br />

the ‘Draghi Plan’ – to drive<br />

down yields. But even this<br />

only provides a temporary<br />

solution, buying time.<br />

o The competitive losses in<br />

the peripheral economies<br />

are so large that external<br />

devaluation (euro exit) will<br />

probably prove more<br />

attractive than internal<br />

devaluation (decade-long<br />

austerity, sharp falls in<br />

wages and massive<br />

unemployment).<br />

o The Draghi Plan is<br />

conditional on peripheral<br />

economies accepting further<br />

austerity measures and an<br />

erosion <strong>of</strong> fiscal sovereignty.<br />

There is no certainty that<br />

countries such as Spain will<br />

sign such a memorandum<br />

with the ‘Troika’ – the ECB,<br />

EU and IMF.<br />

o If the monetary option fails<br />

(monetisation <strong>of</strong> debt), the<br />

fiscal option (mutualisation<br />

<strong>of</strong> debt) is even less likely to<br />

succeed. Hybrid solutions,<br />

such as issuing a banking<br />

licence to the European<br />

Stability Mechanism (ESM)<br />

rescue facility, are not likely<br />

to gain traction.<br />

Still going<br />

down?<br />

Still going down? 21<br />

Graeme Leach, IoD Chief Economist and Director<br />

<strong>of</strong> Policy, looks at the vulnerability <strong>of</strong> the euro<br />

and whether recent interventions by the<br />

European Central Bank have changed the game.<br />

In the Spring edition <strong>of</strong> Big Picture, I argued that the eurozone<br />

was heading for a break-up in 2012. 1<br />

Slightly tongue-in-cheek, I<br />

speculated that the break-up might come in time for some cheap<br />

summer holidays in the ‘Club Med’ economies this year.<br />

Clearly the break-up hasn’t happened yet. Do I still think the euro is<br />

‘going down’? My best response to this question is to quote the<br />

economist Rudiger Dornbusch:<br />

“In economics things take longer to happen than you think they will,<br />

and then they happen faster than you thought they could”.<br />

The main argument <strong>of</strong> this article is that the centrifugal forces<br />

pulling the euro apart are still stronger than the centripetal forces<br />

holding it together. However, the proposed ‘Draghi Plan’ does<br />

provide a temporary way out, if it were to be fully implemented. 2<br />

As<br />

Daily Telegraph economics correspondent Jeremy Warner has<br />

written, “Mr Draghi has at least managed to buy a bit more time.<br />

The endgame has been pushed further, possibly quite a lot further,<br />

into the future”.<br />

The IoD has consistently argued that massive bond purchases by the<br />

ECB (unlimited open market operations) to drive down bond yields<br />

in the peripheral economies would provide a way out <strong>of</strong> the crisis.<br />

Our consistent position has been that it would work, but was highly<br />

unlikely to happen on the required scale.<br />

What has changed recently is that ‘Super Mario’ has managed to<br />

persuade the ECB board – and enough German politicians – that<br />

outright monetary transactions are necessary because the<br />

‘convertibility risk’ <strong>of</strong> the euro is threatened by speculation about a<br />

break-up (see below). Using this argument enables him to outflank<br />

the criticism that bond purchases are merely printing money to<br />

finance public debt.<br />

Speculation alone over the potential impact <strong>of</strong> the Draghi Plan was<br />

sufficient to calm financial markets over the summer, after Mr<br />

Draghi said the ECB would do “whatever it takes to preserve the<br />

euro”. His ‘bring it on’ demeanour towards financial markets<br />

showed just how powerful a role the ECB could take, unleashing<br />

1 Graeme Leach, “This sucker is going down”, Big Picture, Spring 2012, No. 13, pp. 6-15.<br />

2 The German Constitutional Court (GCC) has ruled that the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) and the EU’s<br />

Fiscal Compact are compatible with the country’s Basic Law. However, the GCC ruling is double-edged, because<br />

it effectively blocks Eurobonds and debt pooling and stipulates that any ESM package for Italy or Spain would<br />

require a vote in the Bundestag.


22 Big Picture<br />

“The centrifugal forces<br />

pulling the euro apart<br />

are still stronger than<br />

the centripetal forces<br />

holding it together.”<br />

unlimited firepower to cap yields in the Club Med economies. Super<br />

Mario scared <strong>of</strong>f the bond vigilantes. If the threat was enough to calm<br />

markets, the obvious thought is what would happen if the ECB began to<br />

operate massive bond purchases way in excess <strong>of</strong> its previous Securities<br />

Market programme? (Although sterilisation <strong>of</strong> the purchases means that<br />

outright monetary transactions are not the same as quantitative easing.)<br />

There can be little doubt that massive purchases would drive down yields. 3<br />

The issue is whether or not the ECB will be allowed to engage in<br />

quantitative easing on the required scale. The announcement <strong>of</strong> potentially<br />

unlimited ‘outright monetary transactions’ by the ECB, in the face <strong>of</strong><br />

Bundesbank opposition, is the equivalent <strong>of</strong> drinking at the last chance<br />

saloon for the euro. There would be no credible policy alternative left to<br />

prevent a peripheral break-up, should outright monetary transactions fail.<br />

Speaking about the eurozone crisis, US economist Paul Krugman has<br />

stated that:<br />

“Either the Germans have to accept something they consider unacceptable<br />

(printing money), or they have to accept something that they consider<br />

unacceptable (the break-up <strong>of</strong> the euro).”<br />

Krugman’s point is a simple one. Either the ECB aggressively buys<br />

peripheral debt and caps the borrowing costs <strong>of</strong> the Club Med<br />

economies, or the game is over. This conclusion is the inevitable<br />

consequence <strong>of</strong> crisis-hit eurozone countries having issued debt in a<br />

currency they can’t print.<br />

Let’s examine why.<br />

POSSIBLE POLICY RESPONSES<br />

For ease <strong>of</strong> explanation we’ll examine the four potential policy responses<br />

to the crisis, with the Draghi Plan last <strong>of</strong> all. 4<br />

They are:<br />

1. Political union<br />

The rapid formation <strong>of</strong> a United States <strong>of</strong> Europe – a unitary state –<br />

with a single political entity, single fiscal policy and substantial northsouth<br />

fiscal transfers, would be the ultimate game-changer. But this is<br />

obviously not going to happen any time soon. All too <strong>of</strong>ten the<br />

answer to EU problems is said to be ‘more Europe’, but change on this<br />

scale requires years and decades to effect, not weeks and months. The<br />

challenges to national sovereignty and resistance to fiscal redistribution<br />

are so great that no effective solution is likely from this source.<br />

2. Mutualisation <strong>of</strong> debt<br />

Mutualisation is meant to obscure differences in creditworthiness and<br />

covers a range <strong>of</strong> quasi-fiscal union proposals from common eurozone<br />

debt issuance, to mutualisation above certain thresholds <strong>of</strong> debt, and<br />

rescue facilities such as the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF)<br />

and European Stability Mechanism (ESM).<br />

3 In order to deal with German concerns about deficit financing by printing money, and the inflationary threat, the<br />

outright monetary transactions will focus on the short end <strong>of</strong> the yield curve (one to three-year maturities) and<br />

will also be sterilised (the ECB will take in deposits to counter the expansionary impact <strong>of</strong> outright monetary<br />

transactions on the money supply). Financial market sentiment was also boosted by the announcement that the<br />

ECB will forego seniority and be ranked alongside any other bond holder in the event <strong>of</strong> a default.<br />

4 Theoretically, there is an additional policy option to avoid the peripheral economies departing the euro, namely<br />

that the core economies such as Germany depart the euro instead – leading to a sharp appreciation in the<br />

replacement currency. This would also avoid countries such as Greece facing higher debt servicing costs –<br />

denominated in euros – due to the depreciation <strong>of</strong> any new drachma against the euro. However, such a<br />

scenario is highly unlikely because it would require Germany to be the country that killed the euro – a<br />

fundamental geo-political shift on this scale seems improbable.


“The issue is whether<br />

or not the ECB will be<br />

allowed to engage in<br />

quantitative easing on<br />

the required scale.”<br />

Still going down? 23<br />

Sovereign political opposition to the fiscal option is intense, especially<br />

in northern economies such as Germany and the Netherlands.<br />

German political opposition sees the fiscal option as a handout to<br />

irresponsible governments, and only to be engaged in if very tough<br />

binding fiscal controls are put in place as part <strong>of</strong> any rescue package.<br />

Germany worries about moral hazard – more money has to be<br />

dependent on more fiscal control <strong>of</strong> the peripheral economies,<br />

otherwise there will be even more good money thrown after bad in<br />

the future. The problem, <strong>of</strong> course, is that the loss <strong>of</strong> sovereignty<br />

implied is too high a price for Club Med governments.<br />

Yes, Germany will agree to a form <strong>of</strong> fiscal union, providing its<br />

concerns about moral hazard are met – with a hard, binding fiscal<br />

pact. But unfortunately its concerns about moral hazard are so great<br />

that the political consequences for countries such as Greece and Spain<br />

seem unacceptable.<br />

There are also fundamental challenges to the rescue packages already<br />

agreed, with potential contributors to the funds, such as Spain and<br />

Italy, also at risk <strong>of</strong> being bailed out themselves, putting an even<br />

greater ‘circumscribed’ fiscal burden on the remaining contributors<br />

such as Germany. And underpinning all these debates are the ‘old<br />

arguments’ between Germany and France. The French want political<br />

control over the ECB and the Germans want budgetary discipline.<br />

Negotiations in November, to extend the fiscal adjustment<br />

programme in Greece, only promise temporary respite. And there is<br />

no certainty <strong>of</strong> success in the negotiations. At the time <strong>of</strong> writing,<br />

there is deep disagreement between the IMF and the EU over whether<br />

the country’s 120% <strong>of</strong> GDP debt-target should be put back from 2020<br />

to 2022. At present it is forecast to be an eye-watering 190% in 2013.<br />

Without agreement, Greece may not get its next disbursement, and<br />

could be forced to default. However, some form <strong>of</strong> temporary<br />

compromise is likely – a sticking plaster.


24 Big Picture<br />

CHART 1<br />

The Draghi Plan<br />

Crisis-hit countries New<br />

Primary market<br />

Countries issue<br />

sovereign bonds<br />

Secondary market<br />

Investors trade<br />

in bonds<br />

3. Hybrid schemes<br />

The most significant hybrid scheme is probably the proposal to issue<br />

the ESM rescue facility with a banking licence. This would enable it to<br />

leverage its capital by borrowing potentially unlimited funds from the<br />

ECB – and intervene directly in markets to drive down spreads on<br />

periphery debt. The idea is that this could reinforce the carry trade<br />

incentives in the ECB’s Long-Term Refinancing Operation (LTRO) to<br />

purchase bonds.<br />

However, Germany has all sorts <strong>of</strong> problems with such an approach,<br />

believing it could unleash the beast – potentially unlimited<br />

commitments with little or no control. An immediate problem is that<br />

the ECB is not meant to lend to governments, whilst the rescue funds<br />

are very clearly state institutions. A rescue facility with a banking<br />

licence could engage in bond purchases at primary auctions, 5<br />

something that is anathema to the Germans. To Germany, giving the<br />

ESM a banking licence would be a de facto ability to print money. The<br />

ECB is prevented from buying bonds in primary markets.<br />

4. Monetisation <strong>of</strong> debt<br />

At the end <strong>of</strong> July, ECB President Mario Draghi indicated that plans<br />

were underway for the ECB to intervene in periphery economy bond<br />

markets to drive down yields and put in place yield caps. Merely<br />

suggesting this could happen was enough to inject welcome stability<br />

into financial markets. The new Draghi Plan is the old Securities<br />

Market Programme on an epic scale with bells and whistles.<br />

The Draghi Plan is a combination <strong>of</strong> sensible economics<br />

(conditionality) and slick public relations (convertibility).<br />

1 submit request for aid<br />

2 austerity requirements<br />

3 buys bonds<br />

4 buys bonds<br />

previously: bond purchases only<br />

made under exceptional<br />

circumstances, without conditions<br />

being imposed<br />

European Stability<br />

Mechanism<br />

(ESM)<br />

€<br />

European Central<br />

Bank (ECB)<br />

5 Primary bond markets refer to government debt auctions. Secondary markets trade bonds sold at primary<br />

auctions.


“The new Draghi Plan<br />

is the old Securities<br />

Market Programme on<br />

an epic scale with bells<br />

and whistles.”<br />

Still going down? 25<br />

Instead <strong>of</strong> trying to make the case for ‘printing money’ – always a<br />

difficult sell to the Germans – Draghi has let the emphasis fall on the<br />

issue <strong>of</strong> ‘convertibility risk’. In other words, the existential systemic<br />

threat to the euro warrants aggressive bond purchases to maintain<br />

convertibility, because the functionality <strong>of</strong> the currency is under threat<br />

with a potential break-up.<br />

In the face <strong>of</strong> Bundesbank opposition, the ECB has effectively agreed<br />

to the monetisation <strong>of</strong> debt – printing money to buy bonds in the<br />

secondary market – whilst dressing the policy in the clothes <strong>of</strong><br />

convertibility risk.<br />

But don’t think the Bundesbank or German public opinion can be<br />

ignored. The old issue <strong>of</strong> moral hazard comes to the fore again. If you<br />

buy bonds to drive down yields, what incentive is there for the debtor<br />

nation to impose fiscal austerity measures?<br />

The Draghi Plan attempts to overcome this problem with<br />

conditionality. The ECB will only engage in secondary market<br />

purchases after the country has applied to the EFSF/ESM/IMF for a<br />

bailout – which could also act as the trigger for the rescue fund to<br />

purchase debt in primary auctions. Conditionality requires that in<br />

return for a bailout strictly enforceable conditions are applied.<br />

WILL THE DRAGHI PLAN BE IMPLEMENTED?<br />

Whether or not the Draghi Plan is likely to be fully implemented is a<br />

very moot point. Germany is giving out very mixed messages to it.<br />

Finance Minister Wolfgang Schäuble has said that monetary financing<br />

<strong>of</strong> state deficits is an anathema: “If we start doing that, we won’t<br />

stop”. Bundesbank President Jens Weidman has warned that ECB bond<br />

purchases, even in the secondary market, “could become addictive<br />

like a drug”. Press reports suggest that Weidman threatened to resign<br />

over the issue.<br />

In contrast, Chancellor Merkel and the other German member <strong>of</strong> the<br />

ECB board, Joerg Asmussen, are sending out more positive signals.<br />

Discussing the issue <strong>of</strong> convertibility, Asmussen has stated that, “a<br />

currency can only be stable if its future existence is not in doubt”.<br />

And so the battle lines are drawn, between the traditionalists and the<br />

progressives. The traditionalists argue that the very concept <strong>of</strong> an<br />

independent central bank is under challenge, with the risk that it<br />

could lose control <strong>of</strong> the money supply. The Draghi Plan is almost<br />

certainly a violation <strong>of</strong> the letter and spirit <strong>of</strong> the no bailout clause in<br />

the Maastricht Treaty, with only the lame excuse that the ECB would<br />

be buying debt in the secondary as opposed to the primary market.<br />

Moreover, in the wake <strong>of</strong> the announcement <strong>of</strong> outright monetary<br />

transactions, the German Constitutional Court stated that:<br />

“An acquisition <strong>of</strong> government bonds on the secondary market by the ECB,<br />

aiming at financing the Members’ budgets independently <strong>of</strong> the capital<br />

markets is prohibited as well, as it would circumvent the prohibition <strong>of</strong><br />

monetary financing.”<br />

Traditionalists also point to the potential exposure <strong>of</strong> taxpayers if the<br />

bailout policies go wrong and the Bundesbank and ECB need


26 Big Picture<br />

recapitalising. The bottom line here is the systemic hole 6<br />

at<br />

the heart <strong>of</strong> the euro project – countries don’t control<br />

the currency in which they issue their debt and as a<br />

result there is a liquidity-insolvency negative<br />

feedback loop which could require massive<br />

quantitative easing to overcome, if financial<br />

markets decide a country is bankrupt.<br />

On the other side <strong>of</strong> the battle lines<br />

stand the progressives, who argue that<br />

the very existence <strong>of</strong> the currency is<br />

under threat, that the downside risks<br />

are so immense that exceptional<br />

circumstances call for exceptional<br />

measures, and that the Draghi Plan is<br />

not that exceptional when the<br />

importance and role <strong>of</strong> conditionality is<br />

recognised.<br />

But conditionality also raises its own issues.<br />

Who will blink first? The ECB has indicated<br />

strongly that even with German agreement<br />

(and that <strong>of</strong> other countries with issues, such as<br />

the Netherlands and Finland), the Draghi Plan<br />

could only be implemented and triggered by a debtor<br />

country application to the EFSF/ESM/IMF for a bailout<br />

subject to very strict conditions. Could Greece or Spain sign a<br />

‘fiscal memorandum’ effectively giving up fiscal sovereignty? Could<br />

they sell even more austerity to their electorates? I doubt it. Could<br />

Chancellor Merkel sell weak conditionality and printing money to the<br />

German electorate? I doubt that also.<br />

The practical issues are immense as well. Who decides which bonds<br />

the ECB buys? Who decides the level at which yields are to be<br />

capped? The ECB is not answerable to any Parliament, but it would be<br />

acquiring a quasi-fiscal role.<br />

WHERE DO WE GO FROM HERE?<br />

It is difficult to believe that the status quo can hold. Greece is behind<br />

with its austerity plan, Club Med money supply is contracting,<br />

headline unemployment rates are touching 25% in Greece and Spain,<br />

structural reforms can’t generate the growth to <strong>of</strong>fset the austerity<br />

measures, and there is a yawning gap between the interest rate on<br />

debt and GDP performance – requiring a sustained fiscal primary<br />

surplus (the fiscal balance before interest payments). Something has<br />

to give.<br />

The Draghi Plan, fully implemented, could be the game-changer<br />

which has been lacking over the past two years. We shouldn’t<br />

underestimate its potential firepower. However, the scale <strong>of</strong> its<br />

potential impact is part <strong>of</strong> the reason the Bundesbank opposes it –<br />

because it is a fundamental challenge to the status <strong>of</strong> an independent<br />

central bank.<br />

6 See Graeme Leach, “This sucker is going down”, Big Picture, Spring 2012, No. 13; and Pulse Economic<br />

Outlook, <strong>Institute</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Directors</strong>, December 2011.


“Could Greece or<br />

Spain sign a ‘fiscal<br />

memorandum’<br />

effectively giving up<br />

fiscal sovereignty?<br />

Could they sell even<br />

more austerity to their<br />

electorates?”<br />

Even if the Draghi Plan is fully implemented, it will only buy time. It<br />

won’t provide a permanent solution to the eurozone crisis. In the long<br />

term the competitive losses in the Club Med economies make it very<br />

difficult to believe that all the adjustment will stem from an internal<br />

devaluation – falling wages, austerity and rising unemployment.<br />

What happens if a country such as Greece or Spain backslides on its<br />

austerity plan? Does the ECB stop bond purchases? If it does, the<br />

bond market will implode. If it carries on, German public opinion will<br />

explode. The recent compromise with Greece is probably the limit <strong>of</strong><br />

northern European patience.<br />

Without full implementation <strong>of</strong> the Draghi Plan, the odds favour shortterm<br />

exits from the euro over the next 12-18 months. Even with full<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the Plan there will almost certainly be long-term<br />

exits from the euro. So, to end where we began, yes, the currency is<br />

still likely to go down. The Draghi Plan <strong>of</strong>fers only a glimmer <strong>of</strong> hope<br />

that break-up might not occur.<br />

Mass public demonstrations in Greece in November, against the next<br />

€9.4bn wave <strong>of</strong> public spending cuts, have been followed by a<br />

general strike in Spain. The Greek economy is predicted to contract by<br />

6.5% this year and by 4.5% next year, having already been in<br />

recession for four years!<br />

Eurozone finance ministers have given Greece two more years – until<br />

2016 – to meet deficit reduction targets, but the next tranche <strong>of</strong> loans<br />

cannot be released until there is agreement on how to make Greek<br />

debt sustainable. Any agreement is then subject to ratification by<br />

national Parliaments.<br />

What a mess.<br />

Still going down? 27


28 Big Picture


SNAPSHOT<br />

o The past two years have<br />

seen a noticeable increase<br />

in strike action. The<br />

number <strong>of</strong> working days<br />

lost in 2011 to industrial<br />

disputes was the highest<br />

since 1990.<br />

o Much <strong>of</strong> the regulatory<br />

framework governing<br />

industrial action was forged<br />

in the 1980s and needs to be<br />

updated. This article<br />

presents 10 recommendations<br />

for reform.<br />

o The Government should<br />

introduce a requirement<br />

that 50% <strong>of</strong> union members<br />

balloted in a dispute must<br />

support strike action, not<br />

just a majority <strong>of</strong> those<br />

voting. Electronic voting<br />

should be permitted.<br />

o The information on ballot<br />

papers should be<br />

improved, and a six-month<br />

‘longstop’ date imposed so<br />

that continuing strike<br />

action would need a fresh<br />

mandate.<br />

o Strike bans should be<br />

considered in essential<br />

services in order to protect<br />

key national infrastructure.<br />

o A distinction needs to be<br />

drawn between many<br />

responsible unions in the<br />

private sector which have<br />

agreed to flexibility in<br />

order to save jobs, and the<br />

more confrontational<br />

public sector unions.<br />

Industrial inaction: controlling the super unions 29<br />

Industrial<br />

inaction: controlling<br />

the super unions<br />

Alexander Ehmann, Head <strong>of</strong> Regulation and<br />

Employment at the IoD, looks at the rise <strong>of</strong> the<br />

‘super unions’ and proposes a range <strong>of</strong> reforms<br />

to update the UK’s strike laws.<br />

“The most conservative man in the world is the<br />

British Trade Unionist when you want to change<br />

him.” – Ernest Bevin<br />

1926 REVISITED?<br />

In early September, at the TUC’s 2012 annual Congress in Brighton,<br />

delegates voted overwhelmingly to look into the practicalities <strong>of</strong><br />

organising a general strike in protest at government spending cuts.<br />

The motion, proposed by the Prison Officers’ Union, was seconded<br />

by the National Union <strong>of</strong> Rail, Maritime and Transport Workers<br />

(RMT). Speaking in support, RMT leader Bob Crow said:<br />

Brothers and sisters, we as a<br />

trade union movement have to<br />

stand firm with the leadership and<br />

this gives us an opportunity to<br />

reaffirm our beliefs and reaffirm our<br />

faith for what we stand for. Pass this<br />

resolution, get out on the demo on<br />

October 20th, coordinate action, and<br />

if it means a general strike let’s do it<br />

and get on with it.”<br />

(Applause/Cheers) 1<br />

Later that month, TUC General Secretary Brendan Barber sent a<br />

warm letter <strong>of</strong> support to trade union confederations in Greece as<br />

they embarked on a 24-hour general strike, expressing the “solidarity<br />

<strong>of</strong> the British trade union movement and its six million workers for<br />

your general strike tomorrow to protest against austerity.” 2<br />

Four days<br />

later, Mr. Barber sent a further message <strong>of</strong> solidarity to trade unions<br />

in Spain to support their own call for a general strike on the same<br />

day as the European TUC’s ‘Day <strong>of</strong> Action’. 3<br />

1 Source: TUC, Unedited verbatim report <strong>of</strong> the Tuesday sessions <strong>of</strong> the 2012 Congress, available on the<br />

TUC website: www.tuc.org.uk/the_tuc/tuc-21467-f0.pdf.<br />

2 Available on the TUC website: www.tuc.org.uk/international/tuc-21452-f0.cfm.<br />

3 Available on the TUC website: www.tuc.org.uk/international/tuc-18555-f0.cfm.


30 Big Picture<br />

“At a time when the<br />

economy is emerging<br />

from recession, strikes<br />

could be hugely<br />

damaging for the<br />

prospects <strong>of</strong> recovery.”<br />

CHART 1<br />

The success <strong>of</strong> the September Congress motion compels the TUC to<br />

look at whether a general strike might be feasible, not that one will<br />

necessarily take place. 4<br />

Indeed, in a subsequent interview with the<br />

BBC’s ‘Today’ programme, Brendan Barber downplayed the<br />

possibility. 5<br />

But the ongoing debate has thrown the climate <strong>of</strong><br />

industrial relations into sharp relief.<br />

Much <strong>of</strong> the regulatory framework governing industrial action was<br />

forged in the 1980s. Aspects <strong>of</strong> this framework now need updating, not<br />

only to take into account changes in working practices over the past 30<br />

years, but also to address a more immediate concern. The Government’s<br />

commitment to deficit reduction, and its attendant implications for levels<br />

<strong>of</strong> public spending, appears likely to spark a new wave <strong>of</strong> strikes. At a<br />

time when the economy is tentatively emerging from recession, albeit<br />

with an extremely uncertain and vulnerable outlook, such strikes could<br />

be hugely damaging for the prospects <strong>of</strong> recovery.<br />

INDUSTRIAL ACTION: ON THE RISE<br />

Over the past two years, there has been a noticeable increase in strike<br />

ballots and industrial action. According to the Office for National<br />

Statistics, 1.4 million working days were lost in the UK in 2011 from<br />

149 stoppages <strong>of</strong> work arising from labour disputes. The 2011 ‘days<br />

lost’ figure was the highest since 1990, and the stoppages figure the<br />

highest since 2006 – and considerably higher than the figures for<br />

2010 (92) and 2009 (98). In all, more than 1.5 million workers were<br />

involved in labour disputes during 2011, almost 12 times the number<br />

involved in 2010, and higher than the average number <strong>of</strong> workers<br />

involved in the 1980s. 6<br />

Working days lost due to labour disputes, cumulative 12-month totals<br />

August<br />

2007<br />

August<br />

2008<br />

August<br />

2009<br />

August<br />

2010<br />

August<br />

2011<br />

Source: Office for National Statistics, Labour Disputes Statistics. Data not seasonally adjusted.<br />

Thousands<br />

August<br />

2012<br />

1600<br />

1200<br />

4 “TUC backs ‘general strike’ motion over spending cuts”, BBC News website, 11 September 2012, available at:<br />

www.bbc.co.uk/news/uk-politics-19562394.<br />

5 “Some <strong>of</strong> my colleagues may talk about that [a general strike]. I don't hear too many people calling for a<br />

general strike.” Source: “Anti-austerity marches take place”, BBC News website, 20 October 2012, available at:<br />

www.bbc.co.uk/news/uk-20007496.<br />

6 Source: Labour Disputes, Annual Article 2011, Office for National Statistics, 15 August 2012, p. 3.<br />

800<br />

400


CHART 2<br />

Working days lost in the UK, public/private split, 2002–2011<br />

%<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

Industrial inaction: controlling the super unions 31<br />

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011<br />

Source: Office for National Statistics, Labour Disputes Statistics.<br />

“In 2011, only 51 (5%)<br />

<strong>of</strong> the 964 ballots<br />

calling for strike action<br />

resulted in a negative<br />

vote, a remarkably<br />

low figure.”<br />

Private Public<br />

The latest statistics suggest a similarly high number <strong>of</strong> disputes over<br />

the 12 months to August 2012, with 1.25 million working days lost<br />

from 127 stoppages over that period (see Chart 1). 7<br />

The number <strong>of</strong> strikes in the public sector in 2011 (88) was almost<br />

double the number recorded in 2010 (47), 8<br />

with the number <strong>of</strong><br />

working days lost increasing from 313,100 to 1,267,200. Not only<br />

does this figure account for 92% <strong>of</strong> the total number <strong>of</strong> working days<br />

lost, the ONS also notes that it is a record high since comparable<br />

records began in 1996, and the third time in 10 years that the<br />

number <strong>of</strong> working days lost in the public sector has exceeded 1<br />

million. 9<br />

Chart 2 demonstrates the public/private sector split in the<br />

number <strong>of</strong> working days lost over the period from 2002 to 2011.<br />

There is a further angle to the labour disputes statistics worthy <strong>of</strong> note<br />

beyond the absolute number <strong>of</strong> strikes: the conspicuously high<br />

‘success rate’ <strong>of</strong> strike ballots. Annual trade union ballot data for the<br />

period 2002 to 2011 is presented in Table 1. The table demonstrates<br />

the high percentage <strong>of</strong> ballots calling for strike action that result in<br />

‘yes’ votes, with 94% in 2011 and an average <strong>of</strong> 85% over the past<br />

10 years. In 2011, only 51 (5%) <strong>of</strong> the 964 ballots calling for strike<br />

action resulted in a negative vote, a remarkably low figure.<br />

The figures in Table 1 are strongly suggestive <strong>of</strong> a lack <strong>of</strong> an effective<br />

counterweight to the desire <strong>of</strong> union leaderships to pursue industrial<br />

action. The more recent ballots tell an even more interesting story.<br />

As Table 2 highlights, there have been at least five disputes over the<br />

last year – including the threatened strike <strong>of</strong> Border Agency staff prior<br />

7 Source: Labour Market Statistics, October 2012, Office for National Statistics, 17 October 2012, pp. 11-12.<br />

8 Source: Labour Disputes, Annual Article 2011, Office for National Statistics, 15 August 2012, p. 1 and p. 16.<br />

9 Source: Labour Disputes, Annual Article 2011, Office for National Statistics, 15 August 2012, p. 14.


32 Big Picture<br />

TABLE 1<br />

Trade union ballots 2002–2011<br />

Year<br />

2002<br />

2003<br />

2004<br />

2005<br />

2006<br />

2007<br />

2008<br />

2009<br />

2010<br />

2011<br />

10-year average<br />

Number <strong>of</strong><br />

ballots calling<br />

for ‘strike<br />

action’<br />

738<br />

825<br />

901<br />

781<br />

1,291<br />

713<br />

794<br />

561<br />

555<br />

964<br />

812<br />

Number <strong>of</strong><br />

ballots voting<br />

FOR strike<br />

action<br />

613<br />

684<br />

746<br />

663<br />

1,094<br />

637<br />

658<br />

458<br />

487<br />

904<br />

694<br />

% <strong>of</strong> ballots<br />

voting FOR<br />

strike action<br />

83%<br />

83%<br />

83%<br />

85%<br />

85%<br />

89%<br />

83%<br />

82%<br />

88%<br />

94%<br />

85%<br />

Number <strong>of</strong><br />

ballots voting<br />

AGAINST<br />

strike action<br />

113<br />

125<br />

142<br />

109<br />

140<br />

64<br />

123<br />

93<br />

61<br />

51<br />

Source: Office for National Statistics, Labour Disputes, Annual Article 2011, 15 August 2012, Table 11a, p. 17.<br />

TABLE 2<br />

Turnout and voting patterns in recent strike ballots<br />

Date<br />

July 2012<br />

November 2011<br />

November 2011<br />

November 2011<br />

November 2011<br />

Function (Union)<br />

Border Agency (PCS)<br />

to the London Olympics – in which strike action has been supported<br />

by as little as a quarter <strong>of</strong> those actually balloted. In the case <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Border Agency dispute led by the Public and Commercial Services<br />

(PCS) union, strike action was supported by just 11% <strong>of</strong> those balloted.<br />

REDRESSING THE BALANCE:<br />

REFORMING THE BALLOTING PROCESS<br />

There are a variety <strong>of</strong> contributing factors to the disparity between the<br />

respective levels <strong>of</strong> support <strong>of</strong> those voting and those balloted,<br />

including poor member data and the relatively outmoded paper-based<br />

ballots required for union action. But the fact that an ‘outraged<br />

minority’ can trigger widespread and potentially damaging industrial<br />

action illustrates the clear need to improve the validity <strong>of</strong> the present<br />

ballot system.<br />

Health/Civil service/Local authority (Unite)<br />

Public sector (GMB)<br />

Local government (Unison)<br />

Health (Unison)<br />

Source: IoD compilation from data published by PCS/Unite/GMB/Unison.<br />

Turnout<br />

20%<br />

31%<br />

33%<br />

30%<br />

25%<br />

102<br />

Support (<strong>of</strong><br />

those who<br />

voted)<br />

57%<br />

75%<br />

79%<br />

77%<br />

84%<br />

% <strong>of</strong> ballots<br />

voting<br />

AGAINST<br />

strike action<br />

15%<br />

15%<br />

16%<br />

14%<br />

11%<br />

9%<br />

15%<br />

17%<br />

11%<br />

5%<br />

13%<br />

Support (<strong>of</strong><br />

those<br />

balloted)<br />

11%<br />

23%<br />

26%<br />

23%<br />

21%


“It is necessary to<br />

address the present<br />

situation where<br />

strike action can<br />

be approved for<br />

indefinite periods.”<br />

Industrial inaction: controlling the super unions 33<br />

To achieve that, a higher threshold for strike action should be<br />

instituted. For a strike to be deemed valid, the support <strong>of</strong> a majority <strong>of</strong><br />

both the members voting and <strong>of</strong> the members balloted should be<br />

required – a so-called ‘double lock-in’ vote. However, this move<br />

should be accompanied by a quid pro quo. A key obstacle to securing<br />

greater support for strike action is the current postal ballot system,<br />

which many unions would like to see replaced by an electronic voting<br />

system. Provided that a fair and transparent system <strong>of</strong> electronic<br />

voting can be delivered, there is no reason why – in return for asking<br />

for a higher level <strong>of</strong> legitimacy – the union movement should not be<br />

allowed to embrace technological advances to increase participation.<br />

In addition to these changes, it is necessary to address the present<br />

situation where strike action can be approved for indefinite periods,<br />

with the only requirement being that the first action (i.e. a strike)<br />

must take place within one month <strong>of</strong> the ballot. This acts as a perverse<br />

encouragement to take strike action even if negotiations are ongoing<br />

and making headway. This rule should be abolished and two changes<br />

introduced in its place: a requirement for ballot papers to carry the<br />

detail regarding the precise number <strong>of</strong> strike days being suggested;<br />

and ‘longstop’ dates for successful ballots beyond which they cease to<br />

be effective. An appropriate period for the latter proposal might be<br />

six months.<br />

The first <strong>of</strong> these two changes helps union members to understand<br />

fully what it is they are voting on, including the likely impact <strong>of</strong> strike<br />

action on their employer, its customers, and their own personal<br />

circumstances. It also ensures that union leaders are not given a<br />

mandate for more strike action than the membership believes it had<br />

committed itself to. The second change means that members’ support<br />

for continuing industrial action must be tested again after a period <strong>of</strong><br />

time, when circumstances and attitudes may have changed.<br />

UNION MEMBERSHIP AND THE<br />

EMERGENCE OF ‘SUPER UNIONS’<br />

Alongside the rise in industrial militancy, the other notable feature <strong>of</strong><br />

the union movement’s recent history is its rapid consolidation in<br />

response to diminishing membership. In 1978 the UK had 485<br />

registered trade unions. By 2011, this number had dropped to 154. 10<br />

This reflects a decline in union membership over the same period. In<br />

1978/79, total union membership peaked at in excess <strong>of</strong> 13 million<br />

people; in 2011 approximately 6.4 million employees were trade<br />

union members. 11<br />

An illustrative example <strong>of</strong> union amalgamation can be found in the<br />

experience <strong>of</strong> the National Union <strong>of</strong> Tailors and Garment Workers<br />

(NUTGW). The NUTGW was founded as the Tailors and Garment<br />

Workers' Union in 1920 with the merger <strong>of</strong> the Scottish Operative<br />

Tailors and Tailoresses' Association and the United Garment Workers'<br />

Union. In 1932, it was joined by the Amalgamated Society <strong>of</strong> Tailors<br />

and Tailoresses and renamed itself the ‘National Union <strong>of</strong> Tailors and<br />

Garment Workers’. It was subsequently joined by the United Ladies'<br />

Tailors' Trade Union and the Waterpro<strong>of</strong> Garment Workers' Trade<br />

Union before, in 1991, merging into the General, Municipal,<br />

Boilermakers and Allied Trades Union (GMB).<br />

10 Data from the UK Certification Officer, available here:<br />

www.cert<strong>of</strong>fice.org/CertificationOfficer/files/f6/f696caa2-376a-48f8-bc75-d3d084e71514.pdf.<br />

11 Source: N. Brownlie, Trade Union Membership 2011, Department for Business, Innovation & Skills, April 2012, p. 7.


34 Big Picture<br />

CHART 3<br />

Trade union membership levels in UK from 1892 to 2011<br />

Membership (millions)<br />

14<br />

13<br />

12<br />

11<br />

10<br />

9<br />

8<br />

7<br />

6<br />

5<br />

4<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

0<br />

1892<br />

1895<br />

1898<br />

1901<br />

1904<br />

1907<br />

1910<br />

1913<br />

1916<br />

1919<br />

1922<br />

1925<br />

1928<br />

1931<br />

1934<br />

1937<br />

1940<br />

1943<br />

1946<br />

1949<br />

1952<br />

1955<br />

1958<br />

1961<br />

1964<br />

1967<br />

1970<br />

1973<br />

1976<br />

1979<br />

1982<br />

1985<br />

1988<br />

1991<br />

1994<br />

1997<br />

2000<br />

2003<br />

2006<br />

2009<br />

Source: N. Brownlie, Trade Union Membership 2011, Department for Business, Innovation & Skills, April 2012, Chart 1.1.<br />

“Super unions<br />

covering multiple<br />

employers are able to<br />

co-ordinate strike<br />

action in vast swathes<br />

<strong>of</strong> the economy.”<br />

As will be clear from that brief potted history, until the 1990s the<br />

NUTGW (and its various consolidations) was relatively homogenous.<br />

The mergers that took place were based around broad pr<strong>of</strong>essional<br />

characteristics and all iterations involved the term ‘tailor’ as a<br />

descriptor <strong>of</strong> the union's membership. In 1991, however, the union<br />

was subsumed into the GMB, an entity which refers to itself as<br />

‘Britain’s General Union’. The GMB is now discussing a further merger<br />

with the public sector union Unison to create the UK’s largest union <strong>of</strong><br />

2 million members, spanning both public and private sector employers.<br />

The advent <strong>of</strong> ‘super unions’ such as the GMB has been as common a<br />

development over the last few decades as the demutualisation <strong>of</strong><br />

building societies, prompting a comparison with the ‘too big to fail’<br />

arguments <strong>of</strong>ten levelled at the consolidated financial services sector.<br />

However, unlike the private sector, where mergers are subject to<br />

market and competition scrutiny, the only legislation governing union<br />

mergers requires that members must approve the merger in a ballot.<br />

REDRESSING THE BALANCE: CLIPPING<br />

THE WINGS OF THE SUPER UNIONS<br />

The three largest unions (Unite, Unison and the GMB) – which represent<br />

no specific trade or pr<strong>of</strong>ession – represent over half the total union<br />

membership in the UK. Super unions covering multiple employers are<br />

able to co-ordinate strike action in vast swathes <strong>of</strong> the economy, as was<br />

seen with the public sector strikes in November 2011. Such co-ordinated<br />

action is much harder to achieve where there is a multiplicity <strong>of</strong> unions.<br />

Fewer unions also inevitably means fewer union leaders, which reduces<br />

the prospect <strong>of</strong> dissenting voices bringing balance to debate.<br />

Union consolidation has arguably now gone too far (particularly in the<br />

public sector), and it is necessary to question whether this is enabling


“There is a need to<br />

reverse the ability<br />

for existing super<br />

unions to wield<br />

disproportionate<br />

strike power.”<br />

Industrial inaction: controlling the super unions 35<br />

a disproportionately large power-base to develop against employers<br />

(particularly the Government). 12<br />

The costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> any future<br />

union mergers – to union members themselves, to UK citizens and to<br />

employers – should therefore be very carefully examined. To do that,<br />

new criteria for permitting future amalgamations should be drawn up,<br />

either by establishing a quasi Competition Commission-type body for<br />

unions, or extending the remit <strong>of</strong> the Certification Officer.<br />

Since such a change would only affect future consolidations, there is a<br />

need to remove the ability <strong>of</strong> existing super unions to wield<br />

disproportionate strike power by drawing together a variety <strong>of</strong><br />

employee roles, locations and disputes to deliver maximum impact.<br />

Two actions are necessary:<br />

o An interim requirement to localise workplace disputes, so that<br />

unions negotiate pay at the lowest possible level <strong>of</strong> employer. If a<br />

dispute is specific to a particular school, hospital or local<br />

authority, the ballot and any subsequent strike action should be<br />

limited to these institutions and not the wider union membership<br />

in other locations.<br />

o A full market review <strong>of</strong> the trade union movement as it is<br />

currently structured. An evaluation should be made <strong>of</strong> whether,<br />

akin to the British banking industry, divestment <strong>of</strong> union activities<br />

is necessary to bring greater choice and stability to the union<br />

movement, and to ensure the power to disrupt does not rest in<br />

disproportionately few hands.<br />

PUBLIC AND BUSINESS OPINION<br />

The Ipsos-MORI Research Archive holds data on the studies the<br />

company has conducted into public attitudes towards trade unions<br />

since the mid-1970s. The time series makes clear the significant<br />

impact <strong>of</strong> the 1992 Trade Union and Labour Relations (Consolidation)<br />

Act 13<br />

on public perceptions <strong>of</strong> union power – as Table 3 illustrates. In<br />

September 1978, 82% <strong>of</strong> those polled agreed that the trade unions<br />

had too much power. Since then, the proportion believing the unions<br />

to be too powerful has been on a path <strong>of</strong> generally steady decline,<br />

bottoming out at 24% in August 1995. Intriguingly, though, Ipsos<br />

MORI’s latest survey, conducted in June 2011, found an increase in<br />

concern. At 35%, the proportion agreeing that unions had too much<br />

power is far lower than the high water mark <strong>of</strong> the 1970s and 80s.<br />

Nevertheless, the figure needs to be considered in relation to a<br />

dramatically reduced union membership base. Might this start to<br />

indicate a renewed shift in the balance <strong>of</strong> public opinion?<br />

The business community has typically demonstrated even greater<br />

concern about the extent <strong>of</strong> union power, and held stronger views on<br />

the use <strong>of</strong> strike ballots. To take an example from this year, IoD<br />

members – the majority <strong>of</strong> whom represent small and medium-sized<br />

organisations – were extremely concerned at the potential collateral<br />

12 Quite apart from the impact on UK labour disputes, a lack <strong>of</strong> choice and specialism in union representation is<br />

not necessarily beneficial to the members themselves. Whilst, as Dwight D. Eisenhower rightly noted, “Only a<br />

fool would try to deprive working men and working women <strong>of</strong> their right to join the union <strong>of</strong> their choice”, it is<br />

worth focusing on the word ‘choice’ in that quotation. At present, an employee seeking to be represented faces<br />

the prospect <strong>of</strong> super unions that are increasingly distant from member interests, intent on pursuing a highly<br />

political agenda. The astonishingly low turnouts in union general secretary elections (16% in the Unite election<br />

that elevated Len McCluskey to the top job, for example), arguably evidence a lack <strong>of</strong> interest in these leaders’<br />

political campaigns among the great majority <strong>of</strong> union members.<br />

13 The Act itself was not a single piece <strong>of</strong> legislation, but was the culmination <strong>of</strong> six pieces <strong>of</strong> legislation<br />

introduced from 1980 to 1993.


36 Big Picture<br />

TABLE 3<br />

Proportion <strong>of</strong> public agreeing that “Trade unions have too much power in Britain today”.<br />

October 1975<br />

August 1977<br />

September 1978<br />

September 1979<br />

July 1980<br />

November 1981<br />

August 1982<br />

August 1983<br />

August 1984<br />

August 1989<br />

Dec 1989-Jan 1990<br />

August 1990<br />

February 1992<br />

December 1992<br />

August 1993<br />

August 1994<br />

August 1995<br />

June 2011<br />

Agree (%)<br />

Source: Ipsos MORI, Attitudes to Trade Unions 1975-2011.<br />

75<br />

79<br />

82<br />

80<br />

72<br />

70<br />

71<br />

68<br />

68<br />

41<br />

35<br />

38<br />

27<br />

24<br />

26<br />

26<br />

24<br />

35<br />

Disagree (%)<br />

16<br />

17<br />

16<br />

16<br />

19<br />

22<br />

21<br />

25<br />

24<br />

42<br />

54<br />

45<br />

64<br />

56<br />

55<br />

56<br />

57<br />

52<br />

Net<br />

+59<br />

+62<br />

+66<br />

+64<br />

+53<br />

+48<br />

+50<br />

+43<br />

+44<br />

damage they might suffer during the proposed fuel drivers’ strike. As<br />

Chart 4 illustrates, 82% believed that the strike would have a negative<br />

impact on their business were it to go ahead. Two-fifths <strong>of</strong> directors<br />

believed that the potential impact would be very negative, and only<br />

one in ten believed that their organisation would be unaffected.<br />

Although the strike was ultimately called <strong>of</strong>f, the dispute caused a<br />

great deal <strong>of</strong> uncertainty and disruption as businesses prepared<br />

contingency plans to cope as best they could.<br />

Given the wider business disruption and economic damage that<br />

industrial disputes can cause, it is perhaps not surprising to find<br />

business leaders supporting restrictions on the ability to strike. In<br />

research conducted by the IoD in February 2010, 51% <strong>of</strong> the 1,600<br />

members surveyed supported an outright ban on strikes in the public<br />

sector, and 26% a ban on strikes in the private sector. At present, only<br />

members <strong>of</strong> the armed forces, the police and prison <strong>of</strong>ficers are<br />

banned by law from striking. Table 4 on page 38 shows the degree <strong>of</strong><br />

support among directors for similar strike-prevention legislation in<br />

other sectors and industries.<br />

As Table 4 demonstrates, there is majority support among IoD<br />

members for an outright ban on strike action in 'crucial' services.<br />

These are perceived to extend beyond public services such as the fire<br />

-1<br />

-19<br />

-7<br />

-37<br />

-32<br />

-29<br />

-30<br />

-33<br />

-17


CHART 4<br />

Business concern at potential impact <strong>of</strong> 2012 fuel strike<br />

Industrial inaction: controlling the super unions 37<br />

Q: “Fuel tanker drivers belonging to the Unite union have voted for strike action in a<br />

dispute over working practices. If a strike were to go ahead, what impact would you<br />

expect it to have on your organisation?”<br />

11%<br />

43%<br />

2%<br />

5%<br />

Significant negative impact Slight negative impact<br />

39%<br />

Slight positive impact Significant positive impact<br />

No impact<br />

Source: IoD Policy Voice survey, March/April 2012. 991 members <strong>of</strong> the IoD were polled between 29 March and 4 April.<br />

brigade and the health service, to private sector roles in the electricity<br />

generation and water industries.<br />

The IoD therefore proposes that the Government should consider<br />

prohibiting strikes in a wider set <strong>of</strong> essential services than is presently<br />

covered, such as utility providers. Additionally, in order to protect<br />

against damaging strikes in other ‘near-essential’ services, the current<br />

prohibition on the replacement <strong>of</strong> striking staff with Agency Workers<br />

should be removed. This would allow organisations subject to strike<br />

action to continue providing some services with replacement staff. In<br />

order to make the latter recommendation workable, it is necessary to<br />

secure an accompanying increase in the amount <strong>of</strong> time employers<br />

receive as warning <strong>of</strong> impending strike activity. Two weeks would<br />

ensure that employers have a reasonable chance <strong>of</strong> being able to<br />

put arrangements in place for replacement staff, which the present<br />

one-week notification would not.<br />

TEN RECOMMENDATIONS FOR REFORM<br />

This article has explored business concerns about disproportionately<br />

powerful super unions, the vulnerability <strong>of</strong> key elements <strong>of</strong> our<br />

national infrastructure to industrial action, and the potential exposure<br />

<strong>of</strong> the nascent – but weak – economic recovery to a new wave <strong>of</strong><br />

strikes. That said, it is necessary to recognise that British trade unions<br />

are not inherently destructive. There is a distinction to be drawn<br />

between many mature, responsible unions in the private sector which<br />

during (and since) the financial crisis have agreed to flexibility in order


38 Big Picture<br />

TABLE 4<br />

Restricting the ability to strike<br />

Q: “Do you think that any <strong>of</strong> the following should be prohibited from striking?”<br />

Sector/industry<br />

Fire brigade<br />

Doctors<br />

Nurses<br />

Electricity generation<br />

Water industry<br />

Teachers<br />

London Underground<br />

Postal services<br />

Civil servants<br />

Overground railways<br />

Local government<br />

Airline/airport staff<br />

Bank workers<br />

None <strong>of</strong> the above<br />

Yes (%)<br />

73<br />

67<br />

60<br />

57<br />

53<br />

47<br />

44<br />

43<br />

41<br />

40<br />

40<br />

33<br />

22<br />

21<br />

Yes (number)<br />

1,162<br />

1,059<br />

Source: IoD Policy Voice survey, February 2010. 1,592 members <strong>of</strong> the IoD were polled between 28 January and 11 February.<br />

“The Government’s<br />

approach has been to<br />

tiptoe around the<br />

problem. It should now<br />

be prepared to act to<br />

protect the economy.”<br />

to save jobs, and the politicised, more confrontational public sector<br />

unions.<br />

In the private sector, Ellesmere Port and the resurgent automobile<br />

industry shows the benefits that flexible and intelligent union<br />

engagement can bring. But in public sector monopolies immune from<br />

international competition, union bosses have exploited the inaction <strong>of</strong><br />

successive governments to build positions <strong>of</strong> unbridled power. Their<br />

strangleholds, facilitated by arcane trade union laws, must be<br />

loosened. Since coming to <strong>of</strong>fice in June 2010, the Government’s<br />

approach has largely been to tiptoe around the problem. It should<br />

now be prepared to act to protect the economy – and crucial parts <strong>of</strong><br />

our national infrastructure – from deliberately disruptive sabotage. Box<br />

1 summarises our 10 recommendations for reform.<br />

961<br />

912<br />

850<br />

754<br />

708<br />

690<br />

654<br />

643<br />

631<br />

518<br />

354<br />

337


BOX 1<br />

10 proposals for reforming the UK’s framework <strong>of</strong> strike laws<br />

Industrial inaction: controlling the super unions 39<br />

To address the challenges regarding strike ballots and their legitimacy, the IoD proposes:<br />

1 – A double lock-in vote.<br />

Introduce the requirement that 50% <strong>of</strong> union members balloted must support strike action as well<br />

as a majority <strong>of</strong> those voting.<br />

2 – The introduction <strong>of</strong> electronic voting.<br />

In order to ensure higher participation rates in strike ballots, amend legislation to allow for ballots<br />

to be conducted electronically.<br />

3 – Abolishing the requirement for industrial action to begin within 28 days <strong>of</strong><br />

the ballot.<br />

This will remove the perverse incentive for a union to start strike action in order to keep the ballot<br />

valid, even when negotiations are making promising headway.<br />

4 – Improving ballot paper information.<br />

Require all ballot papers to detail the precise number <strong>of</strong> days <strong>of</strong> industrial action. Strike action<br />

could not exceed these days without a re-ballot <strong>of</strong> members.<br />

5 – A six-month ‘longstop’ date on ballots.<br />

Introduce a period <strong>of</strong> six months from a successful ballot in which strike action can be taken.<br />

Beyond this date, further action beyond the initial six months would require a successful<br />

subsequent ballot <strong>of</strong> union members.<br />

To deal with the challenges regarding union membership and super unions, the IoD proposes:<br />

6 – A quasi ‘Competition Commission for unions’.<br />

The Certification Officer or an alternative body should be given new powers to conduct a market<br />

review into the present impact <strong>of</strong> the consolidation <strong>of</strong> unions, and to introduce new criteria for the<br />

permitted amalgamation <strong>of</strong> unions in the future.<br />

7 – Localised employer ballots/pay bargaining.<br />

Require that unions ballot/negotiate pay at the lowest possible level <strong>of</strong> employer. If a dispute is<br />

school/local authority/hospital-specific, the ballot and strike action should be confined to the<br />

appropriate unit.<br />

To address public and business concerns, the IoD proposes:<br />

8 – A key service strike ban.<br />

Prohibit industrial action in essential services. These would include the fire service, doctors, nurses<br />

and key utility providers.<br />

9 – Remove the prohibition on Agency Workers.<br />

Ensure that organisations that are subject to strike action have the option <strong>of</strong> maintaining their<br />

service levels with the temporary replacement <strong>of</strong> staff with Agency Workers.<br />

10 – Increase the strike notice period.<br />

Increase the length <strong>of</strong> time employers are given as notice <strong>of</strong> impending strike action. The present<br />

one-week notice period should be raised to two weeks to allow for negotiation and any transitional<br />

planning.


40 Big Picture


SNAPSHOT<br />

o Corporation tax distorts the<br />

balance between debt and<br />

equity, imposes heavy<br />

burdens and taxes pr<strong>of</strong>its<br />

that are re-invested. It is grit<br />

in the engine <strong>of</strong> business,<br />

and could be replaced with a<br />

radically different tax on<br />

returns to capital.<br />

o The replacement system<br />

would tax dividend and<br />

interest payments at 30%,<br />

replacing both corporation<br />

tax on pr<strong>of</strong>its and income tax<br />

on these forms <strong>of</strong> income.<br />

o The effective rate would be<br />

far lower than 30%, because<br />

substantial proportions <strong>of</strong><br />

pr<strong>of</strong>its are not paid out, but<br />

are retained for reinvestment.<br />

The overall tax<br />

burden would be<br />

substantially less than<br />

under the current system.<br />

o Total tax would equal<br />

returns that were made<br />

within the circle <strong>of</strong> UK<br />

companies and distributed<br />

outside that circle.<br />

o A system <strong>of</strong> credits would<br />

ensure that payments<br />

through chains <strong>of</strong><br />

companies were not taxed<br />

more than once.<br />

o Special measures would<br />

accommodate new injections<br />

<strong>of</strong> capital, returns <strong>of</strong> capital<br />

and investment overseas.<br />

o Introducing the new system<br />

would be challenging, but<br />

worth the prize.<br />

How to get rid<br />

<strong>of</strong> corporation<br />

tax<br />

RADICAL REFORM OF THE TAX SYSTEM<br />

In May, the 2020 Tax Commission, set up jointly by the <strong>Institute</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Directors</strong> and the Taxpayers’ Alliance, published its report, The<br />

Single Income Tax. 1<br />

The guiding principle was that whenever<br />

income arises, it should be taxed once, and only once, at 30%<br />

(but with a generous personal allowance for each individual, and<br />

with no national insurance charge). The result would be a vastly<br />

simpler and more effective tax system than the one we have now.<br />

We outlined the Commission’s proposals in the previous issue <strong>of</strong><br />

Big Picture. 2<br />

One important type <strong>of</strong> income is returns on capital, whether in the<br />

form <strong>of</strong> dividends or <strong>of</strong> interest. Here, we set out why corporation<br />

tax is ripe for replacement, and how the tax on returns to capital<br />

that the 2020 Tax Commission has proposed as its replacement<br />

would work.<br />

WHAT’S WRONG WITH<br />

CORPORATION TAX?<br />

How to get rid <strong>of</strong> corporation tax 41<br />

Richard Baron, Head <strong>of</strong> Taxation at the IoD,<br />

shows how we could improve the tax system by<br />

eliminating corporation tax.<br />

If an individual engages in a business and makes a pr<strong>of</strong>it, that is<br />

taxed. Since a company has legal personality, it would seem<br />

logical to treat it in the same way, and tax the pr<strong>of</strong>its it makes.<br />

That is what corporation tax does. Each company must compute<br />

its pr<strong>of</strong>its each year, and pay tax on those pr<strong>of</strong>its.<br />

This case for corporation tax is in fact based on a serious<br />

misunderstanding. Companies may have legal personality, and<br />

they may write cheques to HM Revenue & Customs (HMRC), but<br />

they do not in fact suffer tax burdens. They are mere conduits for<br />

economic activity. The sufferers <strong>of</strong> tax are the shareholders, the<br />

employees, the customers (who have to pay higher prices) and the<br />

suppliers (who can only be <strong>of</strong>fered lower prices). If the objective is<br />

to tax returns to capital, it makes sense to cut out the middleman,<br />

and tax the suppliers <strong>of</strong> capital, the shareholders and bondholders,<br />

directly on their returns.<br />

1 Available at: www.iod.com/MainWebSite/Resources/Document/tax_commission_report_2012.pdf.<br />

2 Richard Baron, “The future <strong>of</strong> tax”, Big Picture, Summer 2012, No. 14, pp. 26-33.


42 Big Picture<br />

“There are several<br />

problems with<br />

corporation tax: it<br />

encourages loan<br />

capital over share<br />

capital; it takes a<br />

huge amount <strong>of</strong><br />

work to administer;<br />

and it gives no great<br />

help to companies<br />

that want to invest.”<br />

Under the current system, returns to capital are taxed in two ways:<br />

o Pr<strong>of</strong>its after deducting interest expense (but before deducting<br />

dividends) suffer corporation tax, and there is further tax on<br />

individuals who receive dividends and who pay tax at more than<br />

the basic rate. The income tax rates on individuals are lower than<br />

the tax rates on their other income, reflecting the fact that<br />

corporation tax has already been applied to the pr<strong>of</strong>its.<br />

o Returns on loan capital – that is, interest – are taxed as income<br />

<strong>of</strong> the recipient company or individual.<br />

The result is to tax returns to share capital and returns to loan capital<br />

differently, and that is the first problem with corporation tax. It<br />

encourages loan capital over share capital. The bias is accentuated by<br />

the opportunity to find lenders who will not be taxed on interest<br />

received, either because they are overseas or because they have taxdeductible<br />

losses or expenses to cover their interest income. Indeed,<br />

the use <strong>of</strong> complicated financial structures that exploit the treatment<br />

<strong>of</strong> interest is a major headache for the tax authorities.<br />

The second main problem with corporation tax is that it takes a huge<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> work to administer. Companies would have to compute<br />

their accounting pr<strong>of</strong>its each year in any case, but that is not enough<br />

for tax purposes. Expenditure must be re-categorised, purely for tax<br />

purposes. Many items must be disallowed for tax purposes, including<br />

capital expenditure that is too trivial to capitalise in the accounts.<br />

Special allowances must then be computed for some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

disallowed items. Furthermore, the complexity <strong>of</strong> large businesses<br />

means that merely collecting the data and doing the computations is<br />

not enough. An extra layer <strong>of</strong> controls needs to be added, to ensure<br />

that the computational systems are administered correctly and do<br />

what they are supposed to do. Indeed, a large company must now<br />

appoint a ‘senior accounting <strong>of</strong>ficer’, who must maintain appropriate<br />

systems and certify the state <strong>of</strong> those systems to the Revenue.<br />

Finally, corporation tax gives no great help to companies that want<br />

to invest. Retained and re-invested pr<strong>of</strong>its are subject to corporation<br />

tax, just like distributed pr<strong>of</strong>its. There are tax allowances for<br />

investment in plant and machinery, but these allowances are only<br />

given gradually, and corporation tax must be paid in the meantime.<br />

There are no tax allowances for investment in buildings, apart from<br />

the plant and machinery elements in them.<br />

We would benefit considerably from a system that simply taxed<br />

returns to capital when they were paid out, avoiding the need to<br />

compute taxable pr<strong>of</strong>its, and that did not tax pr<strong>of</strong>its that were<br />

retained for re-investment. Such a system could also treat returns to<br />

debt and equity equally. That is precisely what the 2020 Tax<br />

Commission has proposed.<br />

THE BASIC MECHANISM:<br />

DIVIDENDS AND INTEREST<br />

Under the proposed system, there would be no corporation tax.<br />

Instead, dividends and interest, which represent returns to capital,<br />

would be taxed once, at 30%, and there would be no further<br />

taxation <strong>of</strong> such income.


EXAMPLE 1<br />

How to get rid <strong>of</strong> corporation tax 43<br />

30% might seem high, compared to the corporation tax rate <strong>of</strong> 22%<br />

that the UK will have from 2014 onwards. However, the rate would<br />

replace not just corporation tax, but also income tax that individuals<br />

must pay when they receive dividends or interest. In addition,<br />

substantial amounts <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its are not distributed, and would be taxfree,<br />

instead <strong>of</strong> suffering corporation tax. The overall effective rate<br />

would therefore be a good deal lower than under the current system.<br />

We shall explain the system using examples with dividends, but the<br />

system would be the same for interest.<br />

The objective is to ensure that when a UK company makes a return<br />

on its capital, and that return is paid out to an investor that is either<br />

an individual or a non-UK company, tax is levied. The tax may be<br />

levied when the return leaves the circle <strong>of</strong> UK companies, or it may<br />

be levied earlier, on a payment between UK companies. But it is only<br />

levied once.<br />

The recipient <strong>of</strong> income has the tax liability, but the payer deducts<br />

the tax from the income, and passes it to the Revenue, a bit like PAYE<br />

or the deduction <strong>of</strong> interest on bank accounts at source. There are<br />

two reasons for this approach. The first is that it avoids the need for<br />

millions <strong>of</strong> individuals to complete tax returns and pay tax after the<br />

year-end. The second is that it ensures that tax is collected, even<br />

when the recipient is not a UK taxpayer.<br />

UK company C pays a dividend to shareholder S, where S is an individual or a non-UK company.<br />

C’s pr<strong>of</strong>its to distribute are £100, giving a tax liability <strong>of</strong> £30. C pays £70 to S and £30 to HMRC. There<br />

are no further UK tax liabilities or credits. If S is a foreign individual or company, S may be able to claim<br />

credit for the UK tax suffered against any tax in their own country, depending on that country’s tax laws.<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

£100<br />

£70<br />

C S<br />

£30<br />

HMRC<br />

When a dividend is paid to a UK company, it gets a credit equal to the<br />

net dividend, which it can use to cover its own dividend payment<br />

(Example 2). The generation <strong>of</strong> fresh credits at each step in a chain <strong>of</strong><br />

companies (C to D and D to F in Example 2) would not lead to a<br />

growing mountain <strong>of</strong> credits that could be used to reduce tax,<br />

because each step would use up the credits that had been generated<br />

at the previous step, at the same time as generating fresh credits.<br />

Thus, the quantity <strong>of</strong> credits in existence would never exceed the<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> dividends that had given rise to tax, and that had not yet<br />

left the circle <strong>of</strong> UK companies by being paid to individuals or to non-<br />

UK companies. 3<br />

3 There is an exception to this rule, when investors outside the circle <strong>of</strong> UK companies put capital into the<br />

circle. This is discussed later.


44 Big Picture<br />

EXAMPLE 2<br />

UK company C pays a dividend to UK company D, without a UK-UK election.<br />

C’s pr<strong>of</strong>its to distribute are £100, giving a tax liability <strong>of</strong> £30. C pays £70 to D and £30 to HMRC. C<br />

therefore does exactly the same as in example 1, so C does not need to know whether the shareholder<br />

is a UK company. This will <strong>of</strong>ten be helpful, because companies can have many shareholders, and may<br />

not know the status <strong>of</strong> all <strong>of</strong> them.<br />

D, however, does know that it is a UK company, and it can therefore apply a special treatment to itself.<br />

Moreover, it needs to do so. D may simply pass on the £70 as a dividend to its shareholders, and it<br />

would be quite wrong to impose an additional layer <strong>of</strong> taxation when it does so. The return to capital<br />

was made in C, and should only be taxed once, at the point where C transfers it to D.<br />

D therefore claims from the Revenue dividend credits <strong>of</strong> £70, the net amount it has received from C.<br />

These credits are only accounting entries: the Revenue does not give D any money. The credits entitle D<br />

to pay dividends <strong>of</strong> up to £70 net, to any kind <strong>of</strong> shareholder, without accounting for any tax. The<br />

recipients still have no further tax to pay. But when D makes such payments, it uses up its credits and<br />

they are cancelled.<br />

We may consider two types <strong>of</strong> shareholder, to which D might pay a dividend.<br />

o The first type <strong>of</strong> shareholder is an individual or a non-UK company, S. Then there is nothing<br />

more for the UK tax system to do. The return to capital was made in C, and it was taxed when<br />

the money passed from C to D.<br />

o The second type <strong>of</strong> shareholder is another UK company, F. It is treated exactly like D. It<br />

receives a dividend <strong>of</strong> £70, which represents a return to capital that was taxed when C paid a<br />

dividend to D. F can, therefore, claim dividend credits <strong>of</strong> £70, just like D. When F pays money<br />

out to its shareholders, whom we shall call Z, it can pay dividends <strong>of</strong> up to £70, without<br />

accounting for any tax.<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

£100<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

£100<br />

£70<br />

C D<br />

£30<br />

HMRC<br />

£70 £70<br />

C D F<br />

£30<br />

HMRC<br />

Credit £70:<br />

No tax due<br />

£70<br />

S<br />

Credit £70:<br />

No tax due<br />

£70<br />

Credit £70:<br />

No tax due<br />

Z


EXAMPLE 3<br />

The generation <strong>of</strong> credits could, however, lead to accumulations <strong>of</strong><br />

credits in places where they would be <strong>of</strong> little use. Holding companies<br />

and financial institutions, in particular, would tend to accumulate<br />

credits, because they tend to receive more in dividends or interest<br />

than they pay out in those forms. This accumulation <strong>of</strong> credits would<br />

encourage them to acquire more and more trading businesses, so that<br />

the surplus credits could be used against distributions <strong>of</strong> the pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong><br />

the trading businesses. It would be wrong for the tax system to<br />

encourage such a trend (or to discourage it: the tax system should<br />

avoid influencing patterns <strong>of</strong> ownership in any direction).<br />

In order to avoid such consequences, the 2020 Tax Commission’s plan<br />

would make credits transferable. A UK company with credits that it<br />

did not want to use itself would be entitled to give or sell them to<br />

another UK company. The credits would still have to be generated by<br />

the payment <strong>of</strong> dividends or interest on which tax was actually paid.<br />

Thus the desired result, to levy tax on returns to capital that were<br />

generated by UK companies and paid out to entities that were not UK<br />

companies, would still be achieved.<br />

UK company C pays a dividend to UK company D, under a UK-UK election.<br />

How to get rid <strong>of</strong> corporation tax 45<br />

C is going to distribute pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> £100 to D, which C knows is a UK company. D might, for example, be<br />

C’s holding company, or a major shareholder.<br />

In those circumstances, it would be possible to <strong>of</strong>fer C and D the option <strong>of</strong> a joint election. The effect <strong>of</strong><br />

such a UK-UK election would be that C could pay D the full £100, without accounting for tax.<br />

Correspondingly, D would not acquire any tax credit. If D wanted to pay the money on to its<br />

shareholders, it would have to account for tax in full, or make payments under a further UK-UK election.<br />

Elections could only be made between UK companies. If parts <strong>of</strong> a dividend were going to UK companies<br />

and parts to other types <strong>of</strong> shareholder, only the parts that were going to UK companies could be<br />

covered by elections, and tax would have to be levied on the other parts. This would ensure that tax was<br />

always levied when returns to capital were paid outside the circle <strong>of</strong> UK companies.<br />

INVESTMENT AND DIVESTMENT<br />

The objective is to tax returns to capital, not the investment or the<br />

return <strong>of</strong> the capital itself. But movements <strong>of</strong> capital can be used as a<br />

substitute for returns to capital. For example, buying back a<br />

proportion <strong>of</strong> each shareholder’s shares is just as good a way <strong>of</strong><br />

rewarding shareholders as the payment <strong>of</strong> dividends.<br />

The solution is to treat movements <strong>of</strong> share or loan capital like<br />

payments <strong>of</strong> dividends and interest. Overall, only returns to capital<br />

will get taxed, because the original investment <strong>of</strong> capital will be<br />

matched by the ultimate return <strong>of</strong> capital.


46 Big Picture<br />

EXAMPLE 4<br />

UK company G raises share capital <strong>of</strong> £700 from UK company H, without a UK-UK election,<br />

£800 from UK company J, under a UK-UK election, £1,200 from non-UK company K, and £300<br />

from individual M, a total <strong>of</strong> £3,000. G issues one share per pound received.<br />

The investment by H will be treated like a payment <strong>of</strong> a dividend from H to G. If H has credits to cover the<br />

payment, it will send £700 to G and not account for any tax. H may very well have credits available, because<br />

it may have received capital in the past from individual or non-UK investors, and that will have generated<br />

credits, as explained below. If, however, H does not have credits available, it will send £700 to G and £300 to<br />

HMRC. In either case, it will receive 700 shares. And in either case, G will get dividend credits <strong>of</strong> £700.<br />

The UK-UK election between G and J means that J will send G £800, and will receive 800 shares. No<br />

credits will be used, nothing will be paid to HMRC, and no credits will be generated for G to use.<br />

K will send G £1,200, and will receive 1,200 shares. No tax will be due at this stage, but G will still get<br />

credits <strong>of</strong> £1,200. It might seem odd to allow credits to be generated when no tax has been paid, but<br />

they are generated because money is being injected into the circle <strong>of</strong> UK companies. At some stage, that<br />

money will come out <strong>of</strong> the circle again. That return <strong>of</strong> money injected should not give rise to tax,<br />

whether it occurs on a formal buyback or on the payment <strong>of</strong> dividends. The aim is to tax only returns<br />

that are generated within the circle through the use <strong>of</strong> capital. The generation <strong>of</strong> credits on the injection<br />

<strong>of</strong> capital into the circle will ensure that the return <strong>of</strong> the amount injected will not be taxed.<br />

M will send G £300, and will receive 300 shares. The tax treatment will be the same as the treatment <strong>of</strong><br />

K’s investment, and for the same reason: money is being injected into the circle <strong>of</strong> UK companies. No<br />

tax will be due at this stage, but G will still get credits <strong>of</strong> £300.<br />

TABLE 1<br />

G’s capital-raising<br />

Subscriber<br />

H<br />

J<br />

K<br />

M<br />

Total<br />

Cash to G<br />

£<br />

700<br />

800<br />

1,200<br />

300<br />

3,000<br />

Cash to HMRC<br />

(if no credits used)<br />

At the end <strong>of</strong> this, G will have credits to cover dividend payments, or share buybacks, <strong>of</strong> £2,200.<br />

Furthermore, a buyback will be treated exactly like a dividend payment. If shares held by a UK company<br />

are bought back without a UK-UK election, or shares are bought back from an investor that is not a UK<br />

company, there will be a use <strong>of</strong> credits by G (or a payment <strong>of</strong> tax if G has run out <strong>of</strong> credits), and a<br />

generation <strong>of</strong> credits in a UK company that sells shares back to G. If shares held by a UK company are<br />

bought back under a UK-UK election, there will be no tax consequences. If shares are bought back from<br />

an investor that is not a UK company, there will be a use <strong>of</strong> credits by G (or a payment <strong>of</strong> tax if G has run<br />

out <strong>of</strong> credits), and no further tax consequences.<br />

These tax consequences would only apply to the issue and redemption <strong>of</strong> share and loan capital, not to<br />

trading in the secondary market. There would therefore be scope for distortion. UK companies that wished<br />

to invest in other companies, and that were not <strong>of</strong>fered the option <strong>of</strong> a UK-UK election, might prefer to let<br />

others subscribe and then buy in the secondary market. Investees, on the other hand, would prefer to<br />

receive subscriptions <strong>of</strong> capital from those whose investments would generate credits. The result would be<br />

that issues <strong>of</strong> capital would tend to be to individuals and non-UK companies, which would then sell shares<br />

to UK companies at a pr<strong>of</strong>it. While this problem would be a real one, it should not be too great. Investee<br />

companies would be aware <strong>of</strong> the opportunity for subscribers to pr<strong>of</strong>it by selling their investments, and<br />

would price share and bond issues accordingly. Thus the benefit should be largely captured by the<br />

companies that sought capital to put to productive use. That would be a satisfactory result.<br />

£<br />

300<br />

0<br />

0<br />

0<br />

300<br />

Credits for G to use<br />

against future payouts<br />

£<br />

700<br />

0<br />

1,200<br />

300<br />

2,200


Q pays tax <strong>of</strong> £100, and pays £900 to P.<br />

P gets a credit <strong>of</strong> £900 x (10/90) x (70/30) = £233.33.<br />

INVESTMENT OVERSEAS BY UK COMPANIES<br />

Money does not only come into the UK from abroad. UK companies<br />

also invest capital in non-UK companies.<br />

The suggested approach is illustrated below.<br />

How to get rid <strong>of</strong> corporation tax 47<br />

When a UK company invests capital in a non-UK company, that<br />

should be treated like a dividend payment to a non-UK company. Tax<br />

would be due, except to the extent that credits were available to<br />

cover the payment.<br />

When a UK company receives dividends or interest from a non-UK<br />

company, the desired result is that there should be total tax, UK and<br />

foreign, <strong>of</strong> at least 30% <strong>of</strong> the pr<strong>of</strong>its that give rise to the dividend. If<br />

the foreign tax is less than 30%, the UK should only tax to top the<br />

rate up to 30%. If it is more than 30%, the UK should simply not<br />

impose further tax.<br />

The foreign tax will include both corporation tax on pr<strong>of</strong>its, and<br />

withholding tax on payments abroad.<br />

The way to achieve the desired result is as follows. If the foreign tax<br />

rate exceeds 30%, give a full credit in the UK recipient company for<br />

the amount <strong>of</strong> dividend received. It will then be able to pass the<br />

dividend on to its investors without accounting for any tax. If, on the<br />

other hand, the foreign tax rate is lower than 30%, give a credit (in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> dividends to be paid) <strong>of</strong>:<br />

Dividend received x foreign tax rate x 100 – UK tax rate<br />

100 – foreign UK tax rate<br />

tax rate<br />

Capital returned to the UK company would also generate credits,<br />

even though its return would normally not suffer foreign tax, but it<br />

would only be allowed to generate credits up to the amount <strong>of</strong> the<br />

capital originally invested abroad.<br />

EXAMPLE 5<br />

A UK company, P, which currently has no dividend credits, owns all <strong>of</strong> the shares in a non-UK<br />

company Q, which is based in a country where the tax rate is 10%. Q makes pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> £1,000,<br />

and pays the greatest possible dividend to P. P then pays out all it can to its sole shareholder, an<br />

individual, R.<br />

P pays R £233.33 free <strong>of</strong> tax, leaving it with £666.67. The tax on this, at 30%, is £200.<br />

P pays R a further £466.67, and pays HMRC £200.<br />

R receives £233.33 + £466.67 = £700, just as he would have received on a distribution <strong>of</strong> £1,000 <strong>of</strong><br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it made in the UK.<br />

Total tax collected is £300, made up <strong>of</strong> £100 in Q’s country and £200 in the UK.


48 Big Picture<br />

“The challenge <strong>of</strong><br />

introducing the new<br />

system would be<br />

great, but the prize<br />

would be worth<br />

winning.”<br />

ANTI-AVOIDANCE<br />

A great many tax avoidance opportunities in the existing system<br />

would simply vanish. However, some opportunities would remain,<br />

and measures would be needed to prevent avoidance. These would<br />

include the following.<br />

o Interest can be effectively paid without a loan, or interest, being<br />

apparent at all. Leases <strong>of</strong> assets for the bulk <strong>of</strong> their useful lives<br />

are like this: such a lease is commercially equivalent to the<br />

purchase <strong>of</strong> an asset with a loan. Interest payments that were<br />

wrapped up in such packages would therefore have to be isolated<br />

and taxed.<br />

o Pr<strong>of</strong>its might be distributed to a non-UK holding company by the<br />

holding company over-charging for goods or services, rather than<br />

by the payment <strong>of</strong> dividends. Transfer pricing rules would be<br />

needed to ensure that only market prices were charged for goods<br />

and services.<br />

o In order to prevent a loss <strong>of</strong> tax through UK companies in foreign<br />

ownership making a pr<strong>of</strong>it, then changing their residence to<br />

outside the UK, then making distributions, there would have to<br />

be a deemed distribution <strong>of</strong> all assets when a company ceased to<br />

be resident in the UK.<br />

THE TRANSITION<br />

The transition to the proposed system would markedly change the<br />

tax environment for businesses. In the long term, the change would<br />

be highly beneficial. But the change would create difficulties for some<br />

companies in the short term, and transitional measures would be<br />

needed.<br />

In particular, capital structures that have been designed to be optimal<br />

under the current tax regime would no longer be optimal. The<br />

advantage <strong>of</strong> using debt rather than equity would be removed, and<br />

tax would arise on interest payments where it might not currently<br />

arise. Debt agreements also incorporate clauses that determine what<br />

amounts must be paid if the tax regime changes. Such clauses might<br />

well have adverse effects in the context <strong>of</strong> the change proposed here.<br />

It might well be necessary to continue to apply some features <strong>of</strong> the<br />

existing tax regime to existing debt.<br />

There would also be a number <strong>of</strong> legal issues to manage. The UK has<br />

a large network <strong>of</strong> tax treaties. They were made on the assumption<br />

that the UK would have a corporation tax on pr<strong>of</strong>its, and they also<br />

limit the extent to which tax may be imposed on dividends and<br />

interest paid abroad. These treaties would require revision. Another<br />

concern would be the effect <strong>of</strong> European Union law, which constrains<br />

the policy decisions <strong>of</strong> member states in relation to direct taxes. Such<br />

difficulties should not, however, be insuperable.


“The UK could<br />

advertise itself to the<br />

world as a country with<br />

a very simple regime<br />

for taxing corporate<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>its, and one that<br />

was friendly to<br />

business investment.”<br />

How to get rid <strong>of</strong> corporation tax 49<br />

THE CHALLENGE AND THE PRIZE<br />

The change that is proposed here would allow the UK to advertise<br />

itself to the world as a country with a very simple regime for taxing<br />

corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its, and one that was friendly to business investment.<br />

In particular, the absence <strong>of</strong> tax on pr<strong>of</strong>its that were retained for use<br />

in businesses would give businesses that wanted to invest a far better<br />

deal than the current system <strong>of</strong> tax-deductible depreciation, and<br />

without the complexity <strong>of</strong> the current system. The challenge <strong>of</strong><br />

introducing the new system would be great, but the prize would be<br />

worth winning.


50 Big Picture


SNAPSHOT<br />

o Aviation provides<br />

significant benefits to the<br />

economy, contributing<br />

£50bn to UK GDP, £8bn in<br />

tax, and supporting<br />

921,000 jobs. As the highgrowth<br />

markets continue to<br />

power ahead, flying will<br />

become even more<br />

important.<br />

o Aviation is bad for the<br />

global and local<br />

environment, but quieter<br />

and cleaner aircraft and<br />

improved operational and<br />

ground procedures can<br />

allow aviation to grow in a<br />

sustainable way.<br />

o The UK faces four related<br />

crunches – hub capacity<br />

now; overall capacity in the<br />

South East by 2030;<br />

excessive taxation; and an<br />

unwelcoming visa and<br />

border set-up.<br />

o This article sets out a<br />

holistic aviation plan,<br />

putting forward 25<br />

recommendations to<br />

address six key areas.<br />

1. Making the best shortterm<br />

use <strong>of</strong> existing<br />

capacity.<br />

2. Making speedy decisions<br />

about where new runways<br />

should be built.<br />

3. Surface access and<br />

integration with the wider<br />

transport network.<br />

4. Noise and other<br />

environmental mitigation<br />

measures.<br />

5. Taxation.<br />

6. Visas and borders.<br />

Flying into<br />

the future<br />

Flying into the future 51<br />

In comprehensive new research, Corin Taylor,<br />

Senior Economic Adviser at the IoD, analyses the<br />

constraints on the UK’s airport capacity and sets<br />

out a holistic long-term plan to address the<br />

country’s aviation challenges.<br />

GROWING AVIATION SUSTAINABLY<br />

Aviation is great for the economy, but bad for the environment. In<br />

the current economic climate we need all the growth we can get,<br />

but we also need to preserve our natural world. Fortunately,<br />

technological and operational improvements allow aviation to<br />

grow in a sustainable way.<br />

The economy<br />

Aviation contributes £50bn to UK GDP, supports 921,000 jobs,<br />

contributes nearly £8bn in tax, and generates further benefits<br />

through its role in facilitating tourism. 1<br />

Air transport also supports<br />

trade, with 30% <strong>of</strong> all UK exports by value transported by air and<br />

35 million (m) business passengers passing through UK airports<br />

every year.<br />

The UK and world economies are shifting, and both trends mean<br />

that aviation will be increasingly important. Knowledge-based<br />

services and high-tech manufacturing have both become more<br />

important to the UK economy – and these rely more on air<br />

services than other parts <strong>of</strong> the economy. The high-growth<br />

markets are also accounting for an increasing share <strong>of</strong> global GDP<br />

and UK trade, at the same time as the EU is accounting for a<br />

smaller share – direct long-haul flights to a range <strong>of</strong> new<br />

destinations, primarily in Asia, are therefore vital.<br />

The global environment<br />

According to the Committee on Climate Change, with reasonable<br />

fuel efficiency improvements and a gradual uptake <strong>of</strong> sustainable<br />

bi<strong>of</strong>uels, UK aviation demand can increase by 75-125% on its<br />

2010 level, without carbon dioxide (CO 2) emissions increasing<br />

beyond their 2005 amounts.<br />

Operational measures can also make a large difference. Continuous<br />

descent approaches (CDAs) and continuous climb departures<br />

(CCDs) can reduce CO 2 emissions at these stages <strong>of</strong> the flight (and<br />

can also contribute to lower noise levels). Trials show that making<br />

every stage <strong>of</strong> the flight as efficient as possible (the fuel optimum<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>ile or ‘perfect flight’) can reduce CO 2 emissions by 10%.<br />

1 See: Oxford Economics, Economic Benefits from Air Transport in the UK, 2011, Table 3.1.


52 Big Picture<br />

Improved ground procedures can reduce CO 2 emissions too. A Boeing<br />

747 can consume a tonne <strong>of</strong> fuel and emit several tonnes <strong>of</strong> CO 2<br />

during an average 17-minute taxi to take <strong>of</strong>f. But towing the aircraft<br />

with a tug would use just 20-30 litres <strong>of</strong> fuel. And electric tugs are also<br />

on the horizon.<br />

The local environment<br />

While aircraft noise is a significant concern, the noise footprint <strong>of</strong><br />

airports is tending to shrink rather than grow, as airline fleets become<br />

progressively quieter:<br />

o In 1980, there were 944,000 people living in the 57 decibel (dB)<br />

noise contour around Heathrow. By 2010, that number had<br />

fallen by three-quarters to 228,700. Over the same period, the<br />

number <strong>of</strong> flights rose from 273,000 to 449,000 a year.<br />

o The noise footprint <strong>of</strong> the new Boeing 787 Dreamliner is 60%<br />

smaller than other similarly-sized aeroplanes, while the Airbus<br />

A380 produces three to four-times less noise on landing than<br />

other large aircraft.<br />

It’s not just noise. Air quality also matters:<br />

o The new Bombardier CSeries aircraft will emit up to 50% less<br />

nitrogen oxide (NO x) than current aircraft <strong>of</strong> a similar size, while<br />

successive generations <strong>of</strong> Rolls-Royce Trent engines are becoming<br />

ever cleaner.<br />

o In addition to reducing CO 2 emissions and noise, many <strong>of</strong> the<br />

operational improvements outlined above, including towing<br />

aircraft to and from the runway, will also result in improvements<br />

in air quality.<br />

o Finally, the impact <strong>of</strong> road access to airports, both on carbon<br />

emissions and on local air quality, will fall over time, as car<br />

engines become cleaner and as the uptake <strong>of</strong> electric cars<br />

gradually increases.<br />

THE FOUR CRUNCHES<br />

The UK has always been an open trading nation, and we increasingly<br />

rely on aviation to take our goods and people to the world and to<br />

bring the world to our shores. Unfortunately, as a country, we are<br />

beginning to close up, making it a little harder to get here. As global<br />

trade, tourism and aviation continue to grow rapidly, the UK is<br />

beginning to allow itself to be squeezed, in four related ways.<br />

Crunch 1: South East capacity<br />

The projections in this section quote from the Department for<br />

Transport’s (DfT) 2011 ‘unconstrained demand’ forecasts. We have<br />

used the unconstrained forecasts as they give us the best picture <strong>of</strong><br />

likely demand. Forecasts are liable to be wide <strong>of</strong> the mark – the DfT’s<br />

2000 forecasts overestimated demand growth – but they nevertheless<br />

give us a useful insight.<br />

Overall, the UK has plenty <strong>of</strong> capacity. In 2010, 211m passengers<br />

passed through UK airports, which currently have the capacity to<br />

handle 372m passengers a year. By using the current set <strong>of</strong> runways to<br />

the maximum (which may include constructing new or extended<br />

terminal buildings, lifting planning restrictions and making other<br />

improvements), UK airports would have the capacity to handle 540m


“Overall, the UK has<br />

plenty <strong>of</strong> airport<br />

capacity. The real<br />

issue is where that<br />

capacity is located.”<br />

Flying into the future 53<br />

passengers a year. This is similar to the number <strong>of</strong> passengers<br />

projected to be using UK airports by 2050 (520m).<br />

The real issue is where that capacity is located. The DfT forecasts show<br />

that the South East will need new runway capacity by 2030, but no<br />

airports outside the South East will need new runways before 2040.<br />

o In 2010, 126m passengers used the five London airports –<br />

Heathrow, Gatwick, Stansted, Luton and City.<br />

o These five airports are currently able to handle 181m passengers<br />

a year. By using their current runways to the maximum, that<br />

capacity could be increased to 188m passengers.<br />

o However, the DfT forecasts that 204m passengers will want to fly<br />

from these airports by 2030, and 294m by 2050.<br />

o By contrast, the other UK airports currently have the capacity to<br />

handle 191m passengers a year, a figure that could rise to 352m<br />

if all runways were used to the maximum. But demand is far<br />

lower. In 2010, demand was 85m, a figure forecast to rise to<br />

141m in 2030 and 226m in 2050.<br />

o All <strong>of</strong> the individual airports outside <strong>of</strong> the South East have plenty<br />

<strong>of</strong> spare capacity. No airport outside <strong>of</strong> London will need a new<br />

runway before 2040.<br />

Table 1 sets out the DfT’s capacity assumptions and unconstrained<br />

demand forecasts for each UK airport, up to 2050:<br />

o Areas shaded green are where no new capacity is needed;<br />

o Areas shaded amber show where more terminal capacity and/or<br />

other improvements are required;<br />

o Areas shaded red show where demand is forecast to be larger<br />

than the maximum use <strong>of</strong> the existing runway/s.


54 Big Picture<br />

TABLE 1<br />

Unconstrained demand forecasts for UK airports, 2010-2050 (millions <strong>of</strong> passengers per year)<br />

Airport<br />

Heathrow<br />

Gatwick<br />

Stansted<br />

Luton<br />

London City<br />

Manchester<br />

Birmingham<br />

Edinburgh<br />

Glasgow<br />

Bristol<br />

Liverpool<br />

Belfast International<br />

East Midlands<br />

Newcastle<br />

Aberdeen<br />

Belfast City<br />

Leeds/Bradford<br />

Southampton<br />

Prestwick<br />

Cardiff<br />

Bournemouth<br />

Exeter<br />

Doncaster Sheffield<br />

Humberside<br />

Inverness<br />

Newquay<br />

Norwich<br />

Plymouth<br />

Teesside<br />

Blackpool<br />

Coventry<br />

Total London<br />

Total outside London<br />

TOTAL<br />

“Heathrow has no<br />

more room. No<br />

forecasts are<br />

necessary – the<br />

numbers speak for<br />

themselves.”<br />

Capacity Unconstrained demand<br />

2008 Max use 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050<br />

86<br />

42<br />

35<br />

10<br />

8<br />

30<br />

18<br />

20<br />

12<br />

7<br />

12<br />

10<br />

25<br />

6<br />

5<br />

4<br />

5<br />

5<br />

3<br />

12<br />

2<br />

2<br />

2<br />

1<br />

1<br />

1<br />

2<br />

1<br />

3<br />

3<br />

0<br />

181<br />

192<br />

373<br />

86<br />

42<br />

35<br />

17<br />

8<br />

56<br />

27<br />

20<br />

20<br />

12<br />

20<br />

23<br />

25<br />

20<br />

10<br />

4<br />

12<br />

7<br />

15<br />

12<br />

6<br />

12<br />

2<br />

12<br />

8<br />

3<br />

3<br />

4<br />

10<br />

8<br />

2<br />

188<br />

353<br />

541<br />

Source: Department for Transport, UK Aviation Forecasts, August 2011, unconstrained terminal passenger forecasts by airport (central<br />

forecast). Totals may not sum due to rounding.<br />

65<br />

30<br />

20<br />

8<br />

3<br />

20<br />

9<br />

8<br />

6<br />

5<br />

5<br />

4<br />

4<br />

4<br />

3<br />

2<br />

3<br />

2<br />

2<br />

1<br />


“At current levels for<br />

carbon credits, UK Air<br />

Passenger Duty could<br />

more than <strong>of</strong>fset the<br />

entire emissions <strong>of</strong> the<br />

global air transport<br />

industry.”<br />

CHART 1<br />

Flying into the future 55<br />

o In 2011, Heathrow handled 1.5m tonnes <strong>of</strong> freight, 65% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

total for UK airports. No other UK airport handled more than<br />

300,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> freight.<br />

o In 2010, 36% <strong>of</strong> Heathrow’s passengers were transferring onto<br />

other flights. Of these, 88% were transferring onto international<br />

flights. No other UK airport comes close to this proportion <strong>of</strong><br />

transfer passengers. At Gatwick, the airport with the second<br />

highest proportion <strong>of</strong> transfer passengers, only 8% were<br />

connecting in 2010.<br />

Heathrow’s terminals may be able to accommodate more passengers,<br />

but the airport has a regulated limit <strong>of</strong> 480,000 Air Traffic Movements<br />

(ATMs) a year, and in 2011, ATMs reached 476,000. Under existing<br />

arrangements, Heathrow has no more room. No forecasts are<br />

necessary – the numbers speak for themselves.<br />

Crunch 3: Tax<br />

Since its introduction in 1994, Air Passenger Duty (APD) has risen<br />

from £5 within Europe and £10 outside <strong>of</strong> Europe, to between £13<br />

and £184, depending on the distance and class <strong>of</strong> travel. In 2011-12,<br />

APD raised £2.6bn, a three-fold increase on a decade ago and a<br />

seven-fold increase on 1995-96, the first full year <strong>of</strong> receipts. The UK<br />

now levies the highest taxes on flying in the world.<br />

Only six <strong>of</strong> the 27 EU member countries apply APD. Several countries,<br />

including Ireland, the Netherlands and Denmark, have recently<br />

reduced or abolished it.<br />

APD is levied at a much higher rate than the environmental costs <strong>of</strong><br />

flying would suggest. At the 2007 rates <strong>of</strong> APD, aviation covered its<br />

climate change costs with around £100m to spare. Since 2007, APD<br />

rates have risen substantially. At current levels for carbon credits, APD<br />

could more than <strong>of</strong>fset the entire emissions <strong>of</strong> the global air transport<br />

industry.<br />

Rates <strong>of</strong> UK aviation tax per person compared to EU average<br />

€ 250<br />

€ 200<br />

€ 150<br />

€ 100<br />

€ 50<br />

€ 0<br />

Economy short haul<br />

Economy medium haul Economy long haul Max rate in any class<br />

UK EU average excluding UK<br />

Source: House <strong>of</strong> Commons All-Party Parliamentary Group for Aviation, Inquiry into Aviation Policy and Air Passenger Duty, August 2012, p.10.


56 Big Picture<br />

“The UK trades about<br />

20 times as much with<br />

high-growth countries<br />

with daily (or better)<br />

direct flight<br />

connections as it does<br />

with countries with<br />

poor connectivity.”<br />

Crunch 4: Visas and borders<br />

Since 2010, the UK has tightened up the visa regime for long-term<br />

economic migrants and restricted the ability <strong>of</strong> non-EEA students to<br />

work in this country after completing their studies.<br />

At the same time, the UK has also made it more difficult and timeconsuming<br />

to visit, both for tourism and for business. The UK visitor<br />

visa application process is longer and more expensive than the<br />

Schengen process, costing around 50% more and with a form that<br />

has twice as many questions. It can take up to 12 weeks to process a<br />

UK visitor visa application.<br />

Border queues have also at times been embarrassingly long. Maximum<br />

queuing times have regularly been over two hours. Targets to ensure<br />

that at least 95% <strong>of</strong> non-EEA arrivals wait for a maximum <strong>of</strong> 45<br />

minutes were regularly missed at Heathrow before the Olympics, and<br />

early indications are that performance has started to slip once again,<br />

now that the Games are over.<br />

Why they matter<br />

These four crunches matter immensely, for a number <strong>of</strong> reasons.<br />

Firstly, aviation will become increasingly important to our own<br />

economy as the world economy shifts rapidly towards the highgrowth<br />

markets. By 2050, Goldman Sachs estimates that the BRIC<br />

countries will account for nearly 40% <strong>of</strong> world GDP and emerging<br />

markets overall over 70%. And the UK trades about 20 times as much<br />

with high-growth countries with daily (or better) direct flight<br />

connections as it does with countries with poor connectivity. A similar<br />

pattern holds for investment.<br />

Secondly, there is no doubt that good point-to-point airports are vital,<br />

and direct routes from the UK’s manufacturing heartlands to China’s<br />

growing metropolises would provide an important economic boost. But<br />

the UK already has numerous point-to-point airports. By contrast, it only<br />

has one hub airport, which is already full. Hub airports really do matter.<br />

The key reason for this is that a range <strong>of</strong> routes and a high frequency <strong>of</strong><br />

services are only made viable by the transfer passengers connecting<br />

through a hub airport. 2<br />

And global businesses want to locate in cities<br />

that are well connected, both in range <strong>of</strong> destinations and frequency <strong>of</strong><br />

flights, even if they have to pay a premium in <strong>of</strong>fice rent and salaries to<br />

do so.<br />

Thirdly, Heathrow’s lack <strong>of</strong> spare capacity is already leading to a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> difficulties. In busy periods, planes regularly circle before<br />

landing and queue before taking <strong>of</strong>f, leading to delays and extra<br />

emissions. Heathrow’s number <strong>of</strong> global connections has also shrunk.<br />

The number <strong>of</strong> destinations served by the airport has fallen from 227<br />

in 1990 to 180 today. 3<br />

Heathrow has daily direct flights to 26 cities in<br />

the US and Canada, but to only three in South America. Its market<br />

share <strong>of</strong> European airports serving mainland China (11%) trails rivals<br />

such as Paris (18%). And for many UK regions, the most important<br />

hub airport is now Amsterdam, not Heathrow. 4<br />

Fourthly, it is clear that exorbitant levels <strong>of</strong> Air Passenger Duty are<br />

2 The importance <strong>of</strong> transfer passengers to sustaining routes at Heathrow is illustrated by the fact that in 2010<br />

there were 39 routes at Heathrow on which more than 50% <strong>of</strong> passengers were transferring, and a further 92<br />

routes on which more than 25% <strong>of</strong> passengers were transferring.<br />

3 By contrast, Amsterdam’s Schiphol airport serves 313 destinations, and both Frankfurt and Paris Charles de<br />

Gaulle serve more than 250.<br />

4 Since 1990, the number <strong>of</strong> British regional airports with flights to Heathrow has fallen from 21 to 6. Three times<br />

as many regional airports – 18 – have direct links to Amsterdam.


“The last 50 years <strong>of</strong><br />

aviation policy in the<br />

UK can fairly be<br />

described as a<br />

timeline <strong>of</strong> indecision.”<br />

Flying into the future 57<br />

having a negative impact. APD was one <strong>of</strong> the main reasons cited by<br />

the CEO <strong>of</strong> Air Asia X for pulling out <strong>of</strong> the UK earlier this year, and it<br />

is also now damaging the UK’s regional airports. For example,<br />

passengers flying out <strong>of</strong> Newcastle this year are expected to pay a<br />

total <strong>of</strong> £49m in APD, almost as much as the airport’s turnover last<br />

year <strong>of</strong> £52m. The Netherlands’ short-lived experiment with APD is<br />

revealing. The tax generated €300m but was estimated to have<br />

caused a loss <strong>of</strong> €1.3bn to the broader Dutch economy.<br />

Finally, the UK is not benefitting as much as it could be from the<br />

growth in tourism. In 2011, £18bn was spent by overseas visitors to the<br />

UK. Of this total, just £318m was spent by Indian visitors, £302m by<br />

Brazilian visitors and £259m by Chinese visitors (excluding Hong Kong).<br />

But the opportunity is vast. Chinese visitors (excluding Hong Kong)<br />

spent an average <strong>of</strong> nearly £1,500 per visit, nearly three times the<br />

average for all visitors. Yet the UK attracted just 109,000 Chinese visitors<br />

in 2010, compared to France’s 907,000 and Germany’s 511,000.<br />

A LONG-TERM PLAN FOR GROWTH<br />

The UK requires a holistic aviation plan, to overcome previous failures<br />

to get new runways built, to ensure integration with the wider<br />

transport network and to ensure smoother journeys to and from the<br />

UK. Below we outline the key considerations for that plan, together<br />

with 25 specific policy recommendations.<br />

A holistic plan<br />

The first important consideration underpinning a holistic plan is that<br />

many <strong>of</strong> the proposals that have been made this time around have<br />

been made before. The 2003 Future <strong>of</strong> Air Transport White Paper was<br />

particularly comprehensive, recommending a third runway at Heathrow<br />

and a second runway at Stansted, with land safeguarded for a possible<br />

second runway at Gatwick after 2019. But the White Paper failed to<br />

ensure that additional runways were constructed. Nine years after its<br />

publication, we are effectively back to square one. 5<br />

Indeed, the last 50<br />

years <strong>of</strong> aviation policy in the UK can fairly be described as a timeline <strong>of</strong><br />

indecision, as other countries have expanded their hub airports.<br />

The second consideration is that the main role for government is not a<br />

financial one, with the exception <strong>of</strong> improved surface access to<br />

airports. Rather, central government’s main role is to overcome<br />

planning obstacles by making a firm decision about where new<br />

capacity should go. Outside <strong>of</strong> London, the planning system has not<br />

prevented new runways or runway extensions from being built, but in<br />

the South East, no local council supports a new runway at their local<br />

airport, or the construction <strong>of</strong> a new airport.<br />

The third consideration is that a single solution is not enough. Most<br />

options, in isolation, fail to provide enough extra capacity to meet the<br />

forecast increase in demand. 6<br />

Moreover, given that it will be at least a<br />

decade before any new runway can be opened (and probably closer<br />

to 15 years, considering that the Davies Commission will not conclude<br />

until 2015), a number <strong>of</strong> solutions are needed to address immediate<br />

5 The notable exception to this being that Gatwick has new owners as, shortly, will Stansted – <strong>of</strong>fering the<br />

prospect <strong>of</strong> genuine competition between London’s main airports.<br />

6 London and the South East will have a forecast capacity shortfall <strong>of</strong> 16m in 2030 and 57m in 2040. Hub capacity<br />

will account for almost the entire shortfall. Only a new hub airport or a four-runway Heathrow are sufficient to meet<br />

the shortfall. A combination <strong>of</strong> a third runway at Heathrow and a second runway at Gatwick or Stansted would be<br />

sufficient to meet the overall capacity shortfall, but may not provide enough additional hub capacity.


58 Big Picture<br />

“Heathrow will need a<br />

third runway by 2020<br />

and a fourth by 2030,<br />

while Gatwick will<br />

also need a second<br />

runway by 2030.”<br />

pressures. And capacity cannot be considered separately from other<br />

factors, such as the wider transport network, visas and borders, and<br />

the environment.<br />

In view <strong>of</strong> those considerations, the holistic approach we set out<br />

below covers six principal areas:<br />

o Making best use <strong>of</strong> existing capacity in the short term.<br />

o Making decisions about where increased capacity should go in<br />

the short term, so that new runways can open in the medium term.<br />

o Surface access and integration with the wider transport network.<br />

o Noise and other environmental mitigation measures.<br />

o Taxation.<br />

o Visas and borders.<br />

THE RECOMMENDATIONS<br />

Making best use <strong>of</strong> existing capacity<br />

It is unlikely that any new runways will open within the next 10 years.<br />

The need for short-term measures to make the best use <strong>of</strong> existing<br />

capacity is paramount.<br />

Recommendation 1: Continue with operational freedoms at<br />

Heathrow, but do not introduce mixed-mode.<br />

Operational freedoms can reduce delays, limit stacking and help<br />

Heathrow to recover from disruption. They do not allow an increase in<br />

night flights or flights overall, and can only be used when certain<br />

triggers are met. Mixed-mode, however, should not be introduced. It<br />

would deliver a small increase in capacity for a large increase in noise,<br />

and the planning process would take almost as long as for a third<br />

runway.<br />

Recommendation 2: Reduce the level <strong>of</strong> regulation <strong>of</strong> Stansted and<br />

Gatwick.<br />

Now that Stansted is being sold, the case for the airport having<br />

significant market power, and therefore being subject to price controls,<br />

is weaker. Competition is preferable to regulation, and the new owners<br />

will have a strong incentive to provide an attractive pricing regime to<br />

grow traffic. A similar case can also be made for Gatwick. The current<br />

price control arrangements expire in 2014, the appropriate time for<br />

any deregulation to come into effect. The Civil Aviation Authority<br />

should look again at the market power <strong>of</strong> both airports. In addition,<br />

‘fifth freedoms’ already enjoyed by airports outside the South East<br />

should be extended to Gatwick, Stansted and Luton.<br />

Recommendation 3: Promote airports outside the South East.<br />

All <strong>of</strong> the airports outside the South East have considerable spare<br />

capacity and are part <strong>of</strong> the solution in the short term. Promoting<br />

non-South East airports should include: a campaign overseas;<br />

improving surface access; reducing regulation; introducing codesharing<br />

between rail and air on the West Coast Main Line, primarily<br />

for Birmingham Airport; and introducing a unilateral regional airport<br />

open access policy.


Flying into the future 59<br />

Recommendation 4: Accelerate plans to open up Channel Tunnel<br />

passenger rail services to competition.<br />

Eurostar already has a market share <strong>of</strong> 80% between London and Paris<br />

and Brussels. Competition and direct services to cities such as<br />

Amsterdam and Frankfurt could result in similar shifts to rail for<br />

journeys beyond Paris and Brussels, benefitting the environment and<br />

reducing a little <strong>of</strong> the pressure on Heathrow. The Channel Tunnel has<br />

50% spare capacity for passenger services, but there are several issues<br />

hindering the development <strong>of</strong> competition, which need to be<br />

overcome as soon as possible.<br />

Recommendation 5: Ensure that the remaining parts <strong>of</strong> the Single<br />

European Sky package are implemented swiftly.<br />

The Single European Sky is composed <strong>of</strong> several regulations to create a<br />

pan-European framework for air traffic management. The most<br />

significant change is to re-organise European airspace from national<br />

borders into functional blocks. This should improve the management <strong>of</strong><br />

higher flight volumes, allow more direct flight paths and reduce delays.<br />

New capacity<br />

According to the Department for Transport’s unconstrained demand<br />

forecasts, Heathrow will need a third runway by 2020 and a fourth by<br />

2030, while Gatwick will also need a second runway by 2030. By<br />

contrast, no airport outside <strong>of</strong> the South East will need a new runway<br />

before 2040. The IoD supports the growth <strong>of</strong> airports outside the<br />

South East, but new runways will not be necessary for some time.<br />

A range <strong>of</strong> possible solutions to the UK’s aviation capacity crunch have<br />

been advanced. In the IoD’s view, the two recommendations below<br />

represent the best options for increasing both overall capacity and,<br />

crucially, hub capacity.<br />

Recommendation 6: Allow Heathrow to expand by one, or<br />

preferably two, runways.<br />

Heathrow is the UK’s only hub airport. Unless one or more other<br />

airports can be developed as hubs, the only way to increase the UK’s<br />

hub capacity is to increase Heathrow’s capacity:<br />

o Heathrow is already full – an expansion <strong>of</strong> the airport is therefore<br />

the only option that does not rely on forecast increases in<br />

demand or shifts in the location <strong>of</strong> demand. Heathrow expansion<br />

can be funded privately, without any risks to the taxpayer.<br />

o According to the DfT’s forecasts, demand at Heathrow will<br />

increase to 115m by 2030 and 140m by 2040. This is clearly far<br />

more than a third runway can meet. A fourth runway would meet<br />

a larger proportion <strong>of</strong> the demand shortfall up to 2040. It may<br />

be possible for Gatwick to compete as a hub airport with<br />

Heathrow, but it would be more sensible to see additional<br />

capacity at Gatwick as complementing, rather than competing<br />

with, Heathrow.<br />

o Heathrow is the location <strong>of</strong> choice for airlines. Previous attempts<br />

to move traffic away from Heathrow through the London Traffic<br />

Distribution Rules failed – as soon as the rules were lifted in<br />

1991, Virgin Atlantic moved to Heathrow.


60 Big Picture<br />

o Heathrow is well located for road access and well located for<br />

surface access from London via public transport. The rail<br />

infrastructure improvements currently planned or underway –<br />

including Crossrail, a Western access line to the Great Western<br />

Main Line, HS2, the Piccadilly Line upgrade, and a Southern rail<br />

link to Heathrow – will further improve surface access.<br />

It is outside the IoD’s competence to determine which runway<br />

solutions would be best at Heathrow. We note four possibilities, in<br />

isolation or in possible combination. Further work is clearly needed to<br />

evaluate these options in more detail. Most <strong>of</strong> these options,<br />

unfortunately, involve the demolition <strong>of</strong> a number <strong>of</strong> houses, although<br />

other proposals, including the proposal by Foster and Partners for a<br />

new hub airport, also involve the demolition <strong>of</strong> homes:<br />

o A short third runway to the North, at Sipson.<br />

o A close-parallel runway to the South <strong>of</strong> the existing Southern<br />

runway, which could be contained almost entirely within the<br />

existing airport boundary, together with the demolition <strong>of</strong><br />

Terminal 4 and its relocation to the central area.<br />

o Reconfiguration <strong>of</strong> the runway at RAF Northolt to serve as a third<br />

(or a fourth) runway, with a fast rail link between the terminals.<br />

o The construction <strong>of</strong> two pairs <strong>of</strong> close parallel runways<br />

immediately to the West <strong>of</strong> the existing site, with Terminals 2, 3<br />

and 5 retained and a new Heathrow West terminal.<br />

The downsides <strong>of</strong> Heathrow expansion are noise, local air pollution<br />

and road congestion. They are far more serious issues at Heathrow<br />

than at other possible locations for new capacity. But they are not<br />

insurmountable problems – we set out below how stringent noise and<br />

other environmental measures should be applied, and how public<br />

transport could become the mode <strong>of</strong> choice to access Heathrow.<br />

Recommendation 7: Allow Gatwick to build a second runway.<br />

A second runway at Gatwick airport would complement expansion <strong>of</strong><br />

Heathrow, as well as being important in its own right. Gatwick has<br />

improved remarkably since it was acquired by new owners, and will<br />

continue to grow its traffic. It is already the busiest single runway<br />

airport in the world:<br />

o Gatwick is currently about 80% full, and is likely to be completely<br />

full over the next 15 years. The DfT forecasts show that, even with<br />

expansion <strong>of</strong> Heathrow, demand at Gatwick will increase steadily.<br />

o The airport is well located for rail access, and its rail services will<br />

improve after the Thameslink upgrade is completed in 2018. It is<br />

currently far better located than Stansted for rail access.<br />

o The investment risk would fall on the airport, not the taxpayer.<br />

o It remains to be seen whether London can accommodate two hub<br />

airports, as per New York. A larger Gatwick may remain a very<br />

busy point-to-point airport, or start to develop a hub <strong>of</strong>fering. A<br />

second runway at Gatwick would <strong>of</strong>fer a low-risk way <strong>of</strong> finding<br />

out whether two hub airports in the South East are feasible –<br />

certainly far less risky than Stansted.<br />

Gatwick’s legal agreement with West Sussex Council prevents<br />

construction <strong>of</strong> a new runway before 2019, but there is no reason for<br />

approval not to be granted before that date. This would allow


BOX 1<br />

The main alternative options for increasing airport capacity<br />

Flying into the future 61<br />

Aside from expansion at Heathrow and/or Gatwick, a variety <strong>of</strong> alternative ways <strong>of</strong> increasing the UK’s<br />

airport capacity have been advanced, but all have their drawbacks:<br />

A new hub airport in the Thames estuary or North Kent<br />

o It could only be financed if Heathrow were to close.<br />

o For most people, the new airport would be located on the ‘wrong’ side <strong>of</strong> London and would be<br />

considerably harder to get to by road and rail. In this respect, Hong Kong is not a relevant comparison, as<br />

Hong Kong has no hinterland.<br />

o Rail improvements planned or underway will transform Heathrow’s connectivity. In order to provide good<br />

links to a new Thames estuary airport, this sort <strong>of</strong> rail infrastructure would have to be built (not to<br />

mention new roads), but it is already being built to serve Heathrow.<br />

o Businesses around Heathrow and Heathrow airport workers would be severely disadvantaged.<br />

‘Heathwick’<br />

o Linking an airport that is already full with one that is likely to be full once the rail link opened would be an<br />

expensive way <strong>of</strong> adding no extra capacity at all, although this equation would change if a second runway<br />

was built at Gatwick.<br />

o A long transfer between airports <strong>of</strong> at least 15 minutes would make the hub experience appalling.<br />

Other hub airports <strong>of</strong>fer a quick transfer, <strong>of</strong>ten within the same terminal.<br />

o Heathrow and Gatwick are no longer under the same ownership, reducing the likelihood <strong>of</strong> smooth<br />

operations for passengers transferring between the two airports.<br />

Birmingham airport<br />

o The IoD supports the development <strong>of</strong> Birmingham airport. The runway extension, set to open in 2014,<br />

and code-sharing arrangements with the new West Coast Main Line rail operator, would increase the<br />

airport’s attractiveness.<br />

o However, making full use <strong>of</strong> Birmingham airport would not meet the South East capacity shortfall, and<br />

would add no extra hub capacity. Greater use <strong>of</strong> Birmingham airport should be seen as an interim<br />

measure, before new runways open. It is no substitute for more capacity in the area <strong>of</strong> greatest demand.<br />

A second runway at Stansted<br />

o Over the last few years the airport has stagnated, with passenger numbers falling steadily from 23.8m in<br />

2007 to 18m in 2011. New owners will undoubtedly improve the airport and grow traffic. But Stansted<br />

currently has about 50% spare capacity.<br />

o The airport has no immediate hinterland outside <strong>of</strong> London and would need substantial infrastructure<br />

improvements, including a fast rail link to London, better rail links to the Midlands, and improved road<br />

access via the A14.<br />

o Stansted has not been a location <strong>of</strong> choice for full-service airlines, and is still dominated by Ryanair.<br />

New capacity at Stansted would not be likely to be hub capacity.<br />

A four-runway Stansted<br />

o Many <strong>of</strong> the same arguments apply. At present, demand is only sufficient to fill one half <strong>of</strong> Stansted’s<br />

runway, so building an extra three would risk being a very poor investment.<br />

o A four-runway Stansted would be unlikely to compete effectively with Heathrow, as it is considerably<br />

less well located for surface access.<br />

The best, however, should not be the enemy <strong>of</strong> the good. If the IoD’s preferred options are not feasible, then<br />

expansion <strong>of</strong> Stansted would probably be the next best choice given that it is already there, that much <strong>of</strong> the<br />

surface access infrastructure already exists, and that Heathrow would not need to close to fund construction.<br />

construction to begin after the expiry <strong>of</strong> the legal agreement, and the<br />

runway to open in the mid 2020s.<br />

Gatwick is unlikely to be able to expand beyond a second runway. But<br />

expansion <strong>of</strong> Heathrow and a second runway at Gatwick would be<br />

likely to <strong>of</strong>fer sufficient extra capacity, at least until 2040.


62 Big Picture<br />

Surface access and wider transport integration<br />

The UK has suffered from the failure, over many decades, to<br />

implement an integrated transport policy. Planning rail and airport<br />

developments together, in particular, would maximise the benefits <strong>of</strong><br />

investment in both modes, which is especially important when<br />

resources are limited. The recommendations in this section do depend<br />

somewhat on the airport capacity solutions that are actually chosen –<br />

finite resources mean that those airports building new runways should<br />

be prioritised.<br />

Recommendation 8: Transform Heathrow’s rail connectivity by<br />

constructing the Heathrow Hub and running the HS2 line directly<br />

through Heathrow.<br />

Although rail access to Heathrow will improve dramatically over the<br />

coming years, constructing the ‘Heathrow Hub’ could lead to even<br />

greater benefits. It involves a large station on the Great Western Main<br />

Line with an airport terminal above. Passengers would get <strong>of</strong>f the<br />

train, check in and pass though security at the terminal and board a<br />

fast airside tracked transit to their gate. HS2 should also run through<br />

the Heathrow Hub.<br />

Recommendation 9: Improve and extend rail services to Gatwick.<br />

Gatwick’s rail services will improve when the Thameslink upgrade is<br />

complete in 2018, but more capacity will be needed on services to<br />

Victoria. In addition, better links could be made to the West Coast<br />

Main Line via the West London Line, and to Reading.<br />

Recommendation 10: Extend Crossrail to Stansted.<br />

Extending Crossrail to Stansted would allow direct access to the<br />

airport from a number <strong>of</strong> points in London. It would be preferable to<br />

reducing journey times for the Stansted Express, which only serves<br />

Liverpool Street and Tottenham Hale.<br />

Recommendation 11: Introduce smart ticketing and code-sharing<br />

between rail and air.<br />

For most airports, the most relevant improvement would be to<br />

introduce smart ticketing, removing the need to purchase a ticket prior<br />

to travel and making journeys to and from the airport faster and more<br />

flexible. Existing rail services could all benefit from smart ticketing.<br />

For long distance services to airports, principally Birmingham airport<br />

at present, but potentially Heathrow airport on the Great Western<br />

Main Line and HS2 as well, the most important improvement would<br />

be to introduce code-sharing between rail and air, allowing plane<br />

tickets to be combined with a journey on any relevant rail service.<br />

Noise and other environmental mitigation<br />

If no new capacity is added, then noise and other local environmental<br />

problems will diminish over time, as aircraft steadily become quieter<br />

and cleaner, operational procedures improve and road transport<br />

becomes less polluting. But if new runways are built, then noise and<br />

local air pollution will affect people who are currently less affected, or<br />

not affected at all. Regardless <strong>of</strong> compensation measures, any airports<br />

building new runways (or any new airports) should be subject to the<br />

strictest environmental standards.


Flying into the future 63<br />

Recommendation 12: Airports building new runways, or a new<br />

airport, should be subject to strict noise measures.<br />

No planes above a stringent noise threshold should be permitted to<br />

use the airport, except in an emergency. The noise limits should also<br />

fall further over time.<br />

In addition, the angle <strong>of</strong> descent should be increased above 3 degrees<br />

(the current angle at Heathrow) so that planes are higher above<br />

people’s homes when they land. This would particularly apply to<br />

narrow-bodied aircraft, although it may also be possible to increase<br />

the angle <strong>of</strong> descent for wide-bodied aircraft as well.<br />

Recommendation 13: Airports building new runways, or a new<br />

airport, should be required to implement best practice ground<br />

procedures.<br />

These measures would be important to limit local air pollution and<br />

would include towing aircraft to and from the runways, using fixed<br />

electrical ground power and using electric vehicles for airport<br />

operations.<br />

Recommendation 14: Airports building new runways, or a new<br />

airport, must have a strategy to reduce air pollution and CO 2<br />

resulting from road access to the airport.<br />

Over time, CO 2 and air pollution from road transport will gradually<br />

fall, as engines become cleaner, the uptake <strong>of</strong> hybrid and stop-start<br />

non-hybrid engines increases, and as electric car technology develops.<br />

But these improvements are unlikely to come fast enough, especially<br />

for Heathrow.<br />

A strategy should be adopted to reduce harmful emissions from road<br />

access, with measurable goals. It should both inform, and be informed<br />

by, improvements to public transport services to the airport – if public<br />

transport services are improved, it will be easier to restrict car access.<br />

Recommendation 15: A balance needs to be struck regarding night<br />

flights.<br />

Night flights are by far the most damaging for local communities, but<br />

the solutions are likely to differ between airports. For airports that<br />

serve as express freight gateways, principally East Midlands, Edinburgh<br />

and Stansted, where express couriers operate their own aircraft, a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> night flights do need to be allowed. For airports that build<br />

new runways, flights between 23:00 and 06:00 should be severely<br />

restricted or banned completely. Last year, Frankfurt airport balanced<br />

the opening <strong>of</strong> a fourth runway with a ban on flights between 23:00<br />

and 05:00.<br />

Taxation<br />

The UK levies the highest taxes on flying <strong>of</strong> any country in the world,<br />

reducing our attractiveness as a destination and benefitting European<br />

airports and airlines at the expense <strong>of</strong> UK ones.<br />

Recommendation 16: Freeze Air Passenger Duty (APD) rates in cash<br />

terms.<br />

APD is already too high, but a freeze in cash terms is a necessary first<br />

step.


64 Big Picture<br />

Recommendation 17: Offset the impact <strong>of</strong> the EU Emissions Trading<br />

System (ETS).<br />

Including aviation in the ETS should not add to the overall tax burden<br />

on flying. An allowance should be introduced against APD to cover<br />

100% <strong>of</strong> the impact <strong>of</strong> the ETS.<br />

Recommendation 18: Carry out a comprehensive analysis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

economic impact <strong>of</strong> APD and the ETS.<br />

An economic analysis <strong>of</strong> the total impact <strong>of</strong> APD on growth and<br />

employment in the UK is needed. The review should also establish fare<br />

price elasticities <strong>of</strong> leisure and business travel and investigate the<br />

impacts <strong>of</strong> the ETS charge.<br />

Visas and borders<br />

The benefits <strong>of</strong> more airport capacity, better integration with the<br />

wider transport network and reduced levels <strong>of</strong> taxation would be<br />

considerably reduced if the UK continues to make it difficult and timeconsuming<br />

for people from outside the EU to come to this country.<br />

Recommendation 19: Employ more permanent border staff.<br />

Between March 2011 and March 2012, Border Force staff fell by 10%<br />

at Heathrow and by 6% nationwide, contributing to longer queuing<br />

times. During the Olympics, performance improved because extra<br />

staff were drafted in.<br />

Other things equal, more border staff will mean shorter queuing<br />

times. The use <strong>of</strong> automatic e-gates is increasing, but at the moment<br />

these can only be used by EEA passengers.<br />

Recommendation 20: Modernise Border Force working practices to<br />

maximise the use <strong>of</strong> limited staff resources.<br />

Rosters should be made more flexible, on-call schemes introduced,<br />

and better use made <strong>of</strong> airline passenger information.<br />

Recommendation 21: Accelerate development <strong>of</strong> advance-clearance<br />

systems.<br />

Advance-clearance systems enable passengers on low-risk routes to be<br />

screened by immigration in advance <strong>of</strong> their arrival in the UK and<br />

have the potential to reduce queuing times substantially.<br />

Recommendation 22: Fast-track lanes should not come at the<br />

expense <strong>of</strong> improvements at the border for all visitors.<br />

Fast-track lanes are to be welcomed ins<strong>of</strong>ar as they will smooth the<br />

entry <strong>of</strong> important businesspeople into the UK, but they are no<br />

substitute for improving the border experience for all people entering<br />

this country, for leisure as well as business.<br />

Recommendation 23: Encourage airports to contribute to improved<br />

performance at the border.<br />

People arriving at UK airports do not recognise the administrative<br />

division between the airport operations and the border operations.<br />

Quite naturally they see arrival as one continuous process – landing,<br />

taxiing to the gate, passing through the border, collecting baggage,<br />

and proceeding with their onward journey. It is therefore in the interests<br />

<strong>of</strong> airports themselves that border processes run swiftly and smoothly.


“The UK must end up<br />

with an airports<br />

system that allows for<br />

a flexible response to<br />

changing economic<br />

circumstances, travel<br />

patterns and<br />

technology.”<br />

Recommendation 24: Overhaul the visa application process.<br />

Robust checks need to be carried out, but there are two<br />

improvements that should be made. Firstly, visa processing times need<br />

to be speeded up. UK visas can take up to three months to process, a<br />

deplorably long time. Secondly, there should be better integration<br />

with the Schengen visa application process. It should be possible to<br />

apply for a Schengen visa and a UK visa at the same time, with a<br />

single form containing questions common to both systems followed<br />

by Schengen-specific and UK-specific questions, together with<br />

payment <strong>of</strong> the two fees.<br />

Recommendation 25: Remove international students from the<br />

target for net migration during the period <strong>of</strong> their study.<br />

This is a key move to increase the attractiveness <strong>of</strong> the UK as a<br />

destination for higher education. UK universities are already big export<br />

earners, and the economy benefits more widely from links established<br />

with intelligent and ambitious people from growing economies<br />

overseas who study in the UK.<br />

FLYING INTO THE FUTURE<br />

Flying into the future 65<br />

Above all, the UK must end up with an airports system that allows for<br />

a flexible response to changing economic circumstances, travel<br />

patterns and technology. Most airport expansion projects can be<br />

funded privately. With sufficient capacity growth, there is no reason<br />

why this country cannot continue to be a world-class trading hub,<br />

well connected to all the major economies, today’s and tomorrow’s.<br />

For further in-depth exploration <strong>of</strong> the issues raised in this article,<br />

see the full report, Flying into the future, available on the IoD’s<br />

website at: www.iod.com.


66 Big Picture


SNAPSHOT<br />

o ‘Pr<strong>of</strong>it’ and ‘education’ are<br />

held by many to be<br />

unseemly bedfellows. But<br />

for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies<br />

already play an important<br />

role throughout the sector,<br />

providing nursery and<br />

specialist education,<br />

inspections, qualifications<br />

and a wide range <strong>of</strong> local<br />

authority services.<br />

o It is difficult to justify any<br />

continuing government<br />

policy that prevents forpr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

companies from<br />

competing on a level<br />

playing field in providing<br />

mainstream publiclyfunded<br />

schooling.<br />

o The 2011 Open Public<br />

Services White Paper set<br />

out an ambitious plan to<br />

end government<br />

monopolies in the delivery<br />

<strong>of</strong> public services. But in<br />

practice, innovations like<br />

the Government’s ‘free<br />

schools’ policy are not<br />

nearly bold enough.<br />

o If the Government was<br />

prepared to take its Open<br />

Public Services agenda to<br />

its logical conclusion in<br />

education, then it should<br />

be looking to more radical<br />

solutions, such as the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> ‘education<br />

passports’.<br />

o Until such reforms have<br />

been introduced, the<br />

prospects for<br />

transformational change<br />

within the sector will<br />

remain severely limited.<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>it in education – not a dirty word 67<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>it in<br />

education –<br />

not a dirty<br />

word<br />

James Stanfield, Director <strong>of</strong> Development at the<br />

E.G. West Centre at Newcastle University,<br />

examines the existing role played by for-pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

companies in the education sector, and questions<br />

the prejudice against extending their remit.<br />

In September 2011, Deputy Prime Minister Nick Clegg declared<br />

his support for more diversity and parental choice in education,<br />

but rejected the idea <strong>of</strong> running publicly-funded schools for a<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it:<br />

“To anyone worried that, by expanding the mix <strong>of</strong> providers in our<br />

education system, we are inching towards inserting the pr<strong>of</strong>it motive<br />

into our school system, again, let me reassure you. Yes to greater<br />

diversity; yes to more choice for parents. But no to running schools for<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it, not in our state-funded education sector.” 1<br />

Four months later, in January 2012, the Swedish education<br />

company International Education Schools (IES) became the first<br />

for-pr<strong>of</strong>it company to be awarded a contract (£21m over 10 years)<br />

to run a new publicly-funded ‘free school’. So, where does this<br />

leave the Coalition’s policy on education? Is the UK education<br />

sector now open for business? Or does it remain one <strong>of</strong> the least<br />

attractive service sectors in the UK for private investment and<br />

entrepreneurial talent?<br />

THE EXISTING ROLE OF FOR-PROFIT<br />

COMPANIES IN EDUCATION<br />

Contrary to popular belief, for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies already play an<br />

important role in our state-funded education sector.<br />

Premises, nursery and specialist provision<br />

Every physical item located inside a publicly-funded school,<br />

including the school building itself, has been provided by for-pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

companies operating in highly competitive markets. For-pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

companies also dominate the provision <strong>of</strong> state-funded nursery<br />

schooling in many areas across the country. And for-pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

1 “Nick Clegg rules out running free schools for pr<strong>of</strong>it”, BBC News website, 5 September 2011.


68 Big Picture<br />

“It is difficult to<br />

understand why the<br />

Government is<br />

prepared to allow<br />

for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies<br />

to provide schooling<br />

to children up to the<br />

age <strong>of</strong> five, but not<br />

beyond.”<br />

companies such as the Cambian Group also receive public funds to<br />

help run pupil referral units (PRUs) and specialist schools catering for<br />

children with severe learning difficulties. 2<br />

However, this lies in stark<br />

contrast to the primary and secondary sector where the Government<br />

continues to direct all public funds to government schools, thereby<br />

discriminating against all private alternatives, despite the fact that they<br />

may be able to provide a better quality <strong>of</strong> service. Within the European<br />

Union, there is already widespread government support for a variety <strong>of</strong><br />

private alternatives and the focus is increasingly on what works best.<br />

Greece and the UK are now the only two countries that do not allow<br />

public funds to be distributed to a variety <strong>of</strong> different education<br />

providers. 3<br />

From a public policy perspective, it is therefore very difficult to<br />

understand why the Government is prepared to distribute public<br />

funds to for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies that provide schooling to children up to<br />

the age <strong>of</strong> five, but not beyond that point. Or why such companies<br />

are deemed capable <strong>of</strong> delivering world-class schooling to excluded<br />

children or those with severe learning or emotional difficulties, but not<br />

to all other primary and secondary school children. What logical<br />

explanation could there possibly be for such a dramatic shift in policy<br />

between nursery schooling and primary and secondary schooling?<br />

Local authority services<br />

For-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies also work with local authorities to help deliver a<br />

variety <strong>of</strong> services to schools, from school meals to special educational<br />

needs. For example, Babcock International Plc has entered into a joint<br />

venture with Surrey County Council (Babcock 4S) 4<br />

to provide a range<br />

<strong>of</strong> support services to schools, including consultancy, ICT<br />

programmes, training and development, and project management.<br />

According to the company’s website, Babcock 4S recently presented<br />

Surrey County Council with a £1.2 million dividend as a result <strong>of</strong><br />

efficiencies delivered, whilst continuing to raise education standards.<br />

Other examples <strong>of</strong> for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies providing education services<br />

on behalf <strong>of</strong> local authorities include Arvato Ltd in Sefton, Merseyside;<br />

Devon Norse Ltd in Devon; and Cambridge Education in Islington.<br />

Qualifications and inspections<br />

Edexcel, a for-pr<strong>of</strong>it company owned by Pearson, is the UK's largest<br />

awarding body, <strong>of</strong>fering academic and vocational qualifications and<br />

testing to schools and colleges. Even Ofsted, which has the important<br />

role <strong>of</strong> inspecting schools and maintaining standards across the sector,<br />

relies on a number <strong>of</strong> for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies to carry out the majority <strong>of</strong><br />

its school inspections. Again, this can only beg the question as to why<br />

companies such as Serco and Tribal Group are deemed capable <strong>of</strong><br />

inspecting the quality <strong>of</strong> publicly-funded schools, but not <strong>of</strong> owning<br />

and managing the schools themselves. 5<br />

Common sense suggests that<br />

if these companies have developed a good understanding <strong>of</strong> what a<br />

good school should look like, they will also be better placed than<br />

many to set up, own and manage a publicly-funded school.<br />

2 See: www.cambiangroup.com.<br />

3 See Private Education in the European Union, Eurydice, 2000.<br />

4 See: www.babcock4s.co.uk.<br />

5 The distinction between private sector ownership and private sector management in this debate is<br />

important. While ‘ownership’ refers to a privately-owned school which receives government funds,<br />

‘management’ refers to a government school (or specific services related to the school) being managed by a<br />

private company for a specific period <strong>of</strong> time. When a company owns a school it will obviously have<br />

much more freedom and scope to develop and expand the school.


BOX 1<br />

IES Breckland<br />

Source: http://breckland.iesschools.co.uk.<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>it in education – not a dirty word 69<br />

Free school management<br />

Finally, as noted above, in September 2012 the Swedish education<br />

company International English Schools helped to launch IES Breckland, in<br />

Brandon, Suffolk – the first free school in England managed by a forpr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

company. This suggests that while for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies in principle<br />

are now allowed to manage publicly-funded free schools, public funds<br />

are still not allowed to be distributed to these same companies if they<br />

were to establish exactly the same kind <strong>of</strong> school outside <strong>of</strong> the free<br />

school process. This confusing and contradictory state <strong>of</strong> affairs is a<br />

direct result <strong>of</strong> the Government’s on-going refusal to direct public funds<br />

to a variety <strong>of</strong> different educational providers. As a result, the only way<br />

that it can increase choice and variety within the existing monopoly<br />

structure is to set up new government schools and then outsource the<br />

management <strong>of</strong> these schools to successful private education companies.<br />

In September 2012, IES Breckland became the first free school<br />

in England to be managed by a for-pr<strong>of</strong>it company. According to<br />

the school’s website, “IES Breckland is a school for the future, a<br />

school for the community, a school where children are treated<br />

as individuals. It will be recognised by all as the outstanding<br />

local secondary school, where high standards will be set and<br />

expected from all.<br />

“Our vision for IES Breckland is for it to be a stimulating, secure<br />

and inclusive centre <strong>of</strong> both academic and vocational<br />

excellence in which students from all backgrounds and faiths in<br />

Brandon and its surrounding area are equally valued. We will<br />

together create a school that has, as its core focus, the delivery<br />

<strong>of</strong> high quality secondary education.”<br />

THE PRIVATE EDUCATION SECTOR<br />

The notion that for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies cannot be trusted to, or are not<br />

capable <strong>of</strong>, owning and managing publicly-funded schools is rather<br />

undermined by the scale and success <strong>of</strong> the private education sector.<br />

There are currently 489 mainstream private schools owned and<br />

managed by for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies, educating 82,528 children, which<br />

represents approximately 15% <strong>of</strong> all pupils educated in the<br />

independent sector (82,528 <strong>of</strong> 562,885). 6<br />

Approximately 83% <strong>of</strong> these<br />

schools are non-selective, and 41% charge fees that are similar to the<br />

national average per-pupil funding in the publicly-funded sector.<br />

Outside <strong>of</strong> schooling, there are also hundreds <strong>of</strong> for-pr<strong>of</strong>it education<br />

companies, such as the Early Learning Centre (ELC), which sell a<br />

variety <strong>of</strong> learning products and services direct to parents. The ELC<br />

opened its first store in 1974 and now has 215 stores across the UK,<br />

together with over 80 stores in 19 countries internationally. When<br />

6 James Cr<strong>of</strong>t, Pr<strong>of</strong>it-Making Free Schools, Adam Smith <strong>Institute</strong>, 2010. p. 7.


70 Big Picture<br />

BOX 2<br />

The for-pr<strong>of</strong>it sector in overview<br />

There are 489 independent mainstream for-pr<strong>of</strong>it schools in England educating a total <strong>of</strong><br />

82,528 pupils. The schools in snapshot:<br />

o 72% preparatory (up to age 13)<br />

o Average size 205 pupils<br />

o 83% non-selective<br />

o 80% urban or semi-urban<br />

o 99% secular<br />

o Average fees £7,500 (£3,000 - £15,000)<br />

o Socially and ethnically diverse in terms <strong>of</strong> pupil composition<br />

Source: James Cr<strong>of</strong>t, Pr<strong>of</strong>it-Making Free Schools, Adam Smith <strong>Institute</strong>, 2010.<br />

“To suggest that forpr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

companies are<br />

just out to make a<br />

quick buck from<br />

children’s schooling<br />

is a cheap and<br />

unjustified slur.”<br />

learning materials are purchased from the ELC, it’s doubtful that<br />

parents are concerned with the legal status <strong>of</strong> the Centre or with what<br />

motivates the company to sell its products and services. If the pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

motive plays such an important role in helping companies such as the<br />

ELC meet the learning needs <strong>of</strong> parents and children, why should the<br />

same not also apply if the ELC decided to open and manage a school?<br />

In fact, wouldn’t trusted brands such as Mothercare or the ELC be<br />

particularly well placed to expand into different types <strong>of</strong> schooling if<br />

given the opportunity?<br />

The existing role <strong>of</strong> for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies in both the public and<br />

private education sectors suggests that this type <strong>of</strong> organisation is<br />

already trusted and deemed capable <strong>of</strong> providing a variety <strong>of</strong><br />

educational services. It is therefore difficult to justify any existing<br />

government policy which continues to discriminate against and<br />

restrict for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies from competing with their public<br />

counterparts on an open and level playing field. To claim that forpr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

companies are just out to make a quick buck from children’s<br />

schooling (as suggested by Stephen Twigg, the Shadow Education<br />

Secretary 7<br />

), is a cheap and unjustified slur against the thousands <strong>of</strong><br />

companies and their employees working tirelessly to help deliver a<br />

variety <strong>of</strong> educational services to children across the country.<br />

Of course, this is not to suggest that all for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies operating<br />

in education will always deliver a world-class service. Just as in any<br />

other sector <strong>of</strong> the economy, the level <strong>of</strong> service provided by different<br />

education companies will also differ. However, at the risk <strong>of</strong> stating the<br />

obvious, this will be related to the way in which each company is<br />

managed, not because <strong>of</strong> a fundamental conflict between the pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

motive and children’s schooling.<br />

OPEN PUBLIC SERVICES<br />

An ambitious plan to bring about the end <strong>of</strong> government monopolies<br />

in the delivery <strong>of</strong> public services was set out by the Coalition<br />

Government in its July 2011 Open Public Services White Paper. Writing<br />

7 “Stephen Twigg warns against 'quick buck' school pr<strong>of</strong>it”, Sean Coughlan, BBC News website, 31 May 2012,<br />

available at: www.bbc.co.uk/news/education-18262859.


“If the Government<br />

now recognises the<br />

right <strong>of</strong> patients to<br />

choose health<br />

provider, why can this<br />

approach not now be<br />

applied to education?”<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>it in education – not a dirty word 71<br />

in the Daily Telegraph in May 2012, the Prime Minister outlined his<br />

determination to bring an end to the closed state monopoly where<br />

central government dictates what people get, and how they get it:<br />

“I want truly open public services, where people can choose the hospitals<br />

and schools they go to, with the right information at their fingertips to<br />

make that choice; where different providers, from the private and<br />

voluntary sectors, can come in and <strong>of</strong>fer new services that people can<br />

access free.” 8<br />

Building on the reforms previously introduced by New Labour, the<br />

delivery <strong>of</strong> NHS services has become the first government monopoly to<br />

be challenged. The right <strong>of</strong> patients to choose is now enshrined in the<br />

NHS Constitution. 9<br />

The Any Qualified Provider (AQP) approach,<br />

allowing patients to choose from a list <strong>of</strong> qualified providers – whether<br />

state, charitable or private – when they are referred by their GP, is also<br />

now being rolled out across the NHS. The question <strong>of</strong> whether a<br />

provider <strong>of</strong> health services is non-pr<strong>of</strong>it or for-pr<strong>of</strong>it will therefore<br />

become increasingly irrelevant. Instead, the focus is now on what works<br />

best for each individual patient, and guaranteeing value for money for<br />

the taxpayer. In short, public funds follow the patient. The Government<br />

hopes that choice <strong>of</strong> treatment and provider will become a reality for<br />

patients in the vast majority <strong>of</strong> NHS-funded services by 2013/14.<br />

The rationale <strong>of</strong> this approach is relatively straightforward. Because<br />

there are now a number <strong>of</strong> different organisations that are capable <strong>of</strong><br />

providing similar services, it is impossible for any government to<br />

decide prior to the event which will be the best provider for each<br />

different patient at any one point in time. The only way to guarantee<br />

that each patient gets access to the best possible provider is to allow<br />

each patient to the make the choice themselves. 10<br />

Once again, these<br />

developments raise important questions. If the Government now<br />

recognises the right <strong>of</strong> patients to choose between a variety <strong>of</strong><br />

different health providers, and is now pragmatically focused on what<br />

works best, why can this approach not now be applied to education?<br />

Why should parents not also exercise the right to choose what works<br />

best in terms <strong>of</strong> their children’s education?<br />

FREE SCHOOLS AND HALF MEASURES<br />

Sadly, in education, recent reforms have been much less ambitious<br />

than in health. Despite the increasing role <strong>of</strong> for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies in<br />

the sector, primary and secondary schooling in England remains a<br />

government-controlled monopoly consisting <strong>of</strong> 326 local authorities<br />

and 20,086 government primary and secondary schools, educating a<br />

total <strong>of</strong> 7,451,875 children.<br />

The Government’s flagship policy has been the introduction <strong>of</strong> free<br />

schools, non-selective state schools (or public sector entities funded by<br />

taxpayers), independent <strong>of</strong> local authority control. However, free<br />

schools are not private or independent institutions. While they may be<br />

independent <strong>of</strong> local authority control, they are certainly not<br />

independent <strong>of</strong> the Secretary <strong>of</strong> State for Education or the<br />

8 David Cameron, “Brick by brick, we’re tearing down the big state”, Daily Telegraph, 28 March 2012.<br />

9 The NHS Constitution states that: “You have the right to make choices about your NHS care, and information<br />

to support these choices.” See:<br />

www.nhs.uk/choiceintheNHS/Rightsandpledges/NHSConstitution/Pages/Yourrightstochoice.aspx.<br />

10 In a sign <strong>of</strong> things to come, Circle recently became the first for-pr<strong>of</strong>it company to take over the management<br />

<strong>of</strong> an entire NHS hospital (Hinchingbrooke). It has also opened two brand new hospitals in Reading, which<br />

now provide a variety <strong>of</strong> NHS-funded services. See: www.circlepartnership.co.uk.


72 Big Picture<br />

“For the free schools<br />

policy to be genuinely<br />

transformative, forpr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

education<br />

companies must be<br />

free to open new<br />

schools in response to<br />

demand.”<br />

Department <strong>of</strong> Education. To a certain extent, local government<br />

control has simply been supplanted by central government command,<br />

and while the current Secretary <strong>of</strong> State may be very supportive, it is<br />

impossible to predict what impact a possible change in government<br />

would have on the policy.<br />

While IES Breckland is clearly a positive step in the right direction, it is<br />

unlikely to be replicated across the country by IES or any other forpr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

education company within the existing policy framework. Unless<br />

companies such as IES are allowed to set up new IES free schools as<br />

and where they please, then little progress will be made. Without this<br />

freedom, IES will not be able to realise the benefits that come with<br />

developing a chain <strong>of</strong> schools, and may be reluctant to make longterm<br />

investments in the sector. 11<br />

The pr<strong>of</strong>it motive would play an<br />

important role in the development <strong>of</strong> school chains, as it would<br />

provide companies with a clear incentive to expand and multiply.<br />

Without the pr<strong>of</strong>it motive there will certainly be less <strong>of</strong> an incentive to<br />

replicate success.<br />

It also remains unclear how viable these local non-pr<strong>of</strong>it educational<br />

trusts will be in the long run, especially after those who set them up<br />

have retired. The unpredictable nature <strong>of</strong> these trusts will increase the<br />

risks facing any potential private investor. In the case <strong>of</strong> IES Breckland,<br />

Sabres Education Trust was set up by a small group <strong>of</strong> local parents.<br />

After its application proved successful, the trust then decided to<br />

outsource the management <strong>of</strong> the school to a private education<br />

company. However, this raises questions concerning the role and<br />

purpose <strong>of</strong> the education trust. For example, why not simply miss out<br />

the middle man (the trust) and allow for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies to apply,<br />

set up and manage free schools themselves?<br />

All <strong>of</strong> this confusion suggests that the Government has failed to make<br />

a clear distinction between parental demand (groups <strong>of</strong> parents<br />

demanding a new school in their local area), and the ability <strong>of</strong> these<br />

groups to set up and run a school themselves. However, there is<br />

clearly an important difference between the two. If parents want a<br />

new school in their local area, then the only option they currently<br />

have is to set up a new free school themselves. But in a normal, open<br />

market, where there was excess parental demand in a specific<br />

geographical area you would expect a number <strong>of</strong> education<br />

companies, either local, national or global, to be attracted to the<br />

location. And as soon as one provider showed an interest, more would<br />

be expected to follow.<br />

For the free schools policy to be genuinely transformative, for-pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

education companies must be free to <strong>of</strong>fer their services to parents<br />

and open new schools in response to demand. If they remain fettered,<br />

the impact <strong>of</strong> free schools is likely to be muted. The number <strong>of</strong> new<br />

free schools being introduced represents a very small proportion <strong>of</strong><br />

the school population indeed. By the end <strong>of</strong> 2013, there will be an<br />

estimated 193 free schools – with only a handful <strong>of</strong> these being run<br />

by for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies. In other words, the projected number <strong>of</strong> free<br />

schools by the end <strong>of</strong> 2013 will represent just 1% <strong>of</strong> publicly-funded<br />

schools in England. Without reform, therefore, the Government’s free<br />

school policy is likely to result in the opening <strong>of</strong> a relatively small<br />

number <strong>of</strong> new schools, but will do nothing to tackle the problems<br />

which continue to plague the rest <strong>of</strong> the sector. While free schools are<br />

11 For a more detailed discussion about the benefits <strong>of</strong> chains see James O’Shaughnessy, Competition<br />

Meets Collaboration: Helping school chains address England’s long tail <strong>of</strong> educational failure, Policy<br />

Exchange, October 2012.


“Without reform, the<br />

Government’s free<br />

school policy will do<br />

nothing to tackle the<br />

problems plaguing the<br />

rest <strong>of</strong> the sector.”<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>it in education – not a dirty word 73<br />

a welcome initiative, they should be celebrated as a glimmering <strong>of</strong><br />

what an open and entrepreneurial environment makes possible – not<br />

as the culmination <strong>of</strong> that process.<br />

To give credit where it is due, the Coalition Government has<br />

dramatically increased the number <strong>of</strong> academies in England, from 203<br />

in May 2010 to 1,807 by May 2012. Academies enjoy the same<br />

freedoms as free schools, but are former local authority schools<br />

instead <strong>of</strong> entirely new schools. To date, though, for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies<br />

have been restricted from managing academies, which suggests that<br />

the Government’s policy on academies is now lagging behind its<br />

policy on free schools. For consistency, and to allow the academy<br />

programme to fulfil its potential, these restrictions also need to be<br />

removed and for-pr<strong>of</strong>it companies permitted to develop and manage<br />

chains <strong>of</strong> academies across the country.<br />

THE EDUCATION PASSPORT<br />

If the Government is prepared to take its Open Public Services agenda to<br />

its logical conclusion in education, and is genuinely interested in what<br />

works best, then it should be looking to more radical solutions. In<br />

particular, it should be seeking to address the fundamental flaw in the<br />

vast majority <strong>of</strong> state education systems around the world –<br />

governments’ propensity to distribute public funds to institutions rather<br />

than to parents. As soon as this happens, governments tend to set up<br />

their own schools which then crowd out the majority <strong>of</strong> private<br />

alternatives. The result: government monopoly. With governments then<br />

responsible for the majority <strong>of</strong> schools across the country, they have<br />

little option but to get involved with almost every aspect <strong>of</strong> how those<br />

government schools operate and what they teach.<br />

To break this cycle, the Government could do worse than to examine<br />

the system <strong>of</strong> ‘education passports’ put forward by the <strong>Institute</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Directors</strong> in 1999. 12<br />

These payment passports are analogous to<br />

education vouchers in the economic literature. The IoD argued that a<br />

voucher system with a top-up facility could create a truly world-class<br />

12 Graeme Leach, Choice, Choice, Choice, <strong>Institute</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Directors</strong>, 1999.


74 Big Picture<br />

“The Government needs<br />

to address the<br />

fundamental flaw in<br />

state education systems<br />

around the world – the<br />

propensity to distribute<br />

funds to institutions<br />

rather than parents.”<br />

education system for the 21st century. If parents chose to send their<br />

children to existing state schools, and not exercise any top-up option<br />

at a private school, then education would remain free at the point <strong>of</strong><br />

use. In advancing the new system, the IoD also pointed out that the<br />

debate over market forces in education is not new, quoting John<br />

Stuart Mill, from On Liberty:<br />

“If the government would make up its mind to require for every child a<br />

good education, it might save itself the trouble <strong>of</strong> providing one. It might<br />

leave to parents to obtain the education where and how they pleased,<br />

and content itself to helping pay the school fees... an education<br />

established and controlled by the state should only exist, if it exists at all,<br />

as one among many competing experiments.”<br />

In a universal system <strong>of</strong> education passports, all public funds would be<br />

directed to parents, not schools, with parents then free to choose their<br />

preferred school. As a result, all questions relating to who should be<br />

allowed to set up a new school, or whether a new school should be<br />

permitted at all, would no longer be the concern <strong>of</strong> politicians, civil<br />

servants, academics or policy experts. Instead, the Government would<br />

simply give purchasing power to parents, who would be responsible<br />

for choosing between different types <strong>of</strong> provision. As in the NHS, this<br />

is the only way to guarantee that people get access to the best<br />

opportunities available.<br />

The three basic principles <strong>of</strong> the education passport system are as follows:<br />

o The value <strong>of</strong> the passport is the average cost <strong>of</strong> a state school place;<br />

o Parents are allowed to top up the payment with their own<br />

contribution towards fees;<br />

o Both parents and schools are unconstrained – parents can spend<br />

the voucher payment at any publicly-funded or private school<br />

and these schools have freedom over their waiting list choices.<br />

Since the IoD initially recommended this reform over a decade ago,<br />

nothing has changed with reference to the fundamental problem<br />

facing the sector referenced above – that the Government directs<br />

public funds to schools instead <strong>of</strong> parents. Until this very simple and<br />

common sense reform has been introduced, the prospects for<br />

transformational change within the sector will remain severely limited.<br />

The current controversy surrounding the role <strong>of</strong> the pr<strong>of</strong>it motive in<br />

education is therefore best viewed as a red herring. Instead, two key<br />

questions prevail. First, should parents have the right and freedom to<br />

choose the nature and form <strong>of</strong> education which their children receive,<br />

or should the government continue to dictate? Second, should our<br />

education sector be open and inclusive, allowing a variety <strong>of</strong> different<br />

providers to compete on a fair and level playing field? When Milton<br />

Friedman was interviewed in 2003, he was questioned about his<br />

future vision <strong>of</strong> education and whether he thought that schooling<br />

would be provided exclusively by the for-pr<strong>of</strong>it sector. His reply<br />

encapsulates one <strong>of</strong> the principal tenets <strong>of</strong> this article:<br />

“No, I see competition. Let parents choose. I would expect an open<br />

market where there would be a wide variety <strong>of</strong> schools. There would be<br />

for-pr<strong>of</strong>it schools, charter schools, parochial schools, and government<br />

schools. Which survived would depend on which ones satisfied their<br />

customers.” 13<br />

13 Milton Friedman, quoted in “Choice and Freedom”, Education Next, Winter 2003, Vol. 3, No. 1.


Pr<strong>of</strong>it in education – not a dirty word 75


76 Big Picture


SNAPSHOT<br />

o For the first time in history<br />

the number <strong>of</strong> people<br />

living in urban areas now<br />

exceeds those in rural<br />

areas. By 2050, two-thirds<br />

<strong>of</strong> the world’s population<br />

is expected to live in<br />

urban areas.<br />

o The future is almost certain<br />

to be characterised by more<br />

and bigger ‘megacities’ –<br />

those with a population<br />

above 10 million.<br />

o By 2025, emerging<br />

economies are expected to<br />

account for two-thirds <strong>of</strong><br />

the world’s largest urban<br />

agglomerations.<br />

o Most <strong>of</strong> the globe’s urban<br />

dwellers currently live in<br />

cities <strong>of</strong> fewer than<br />

500,000 people.<br />

o The nature <strong>of</strong> cities is likely<br />

to change, with the<br />

‘aerotropolis’ concept an<br />

example <strong>of</strong> how future<br />

competitive success could<br />

be dependent on<br />

developing a city around an<br />

airport, rather than the<br />

other way around.<br />

o Future competitiveness<br />

between cities will be<br />

based on connectivity and<br />

the survival <strong>of</strong> the fastest.<br />

In many instances<br />

emerging economies are<br />

leading the way.<br />

Future cities – the survival <strong>of</strong> the fastest 77<br />

Future cities –<br />

the survival<br />

<strong>of</strong> the fastest<br />

William Moore, Economic Intern at the IoD,<br />

examines the future dynamics <strong>of</strong> cities.<br />

THE FUTURE URBAN LANDSCAPE<br />

If you don’t think about cities, think about this statistic. According<br />

to McKinsey, between now and 2025, 65% <strong>of</strong> global GDP growth<br />

will be in 600 cities.<br />

In 2008, the number <strong>of</strong> people worldwide living in urban areas<br />

exceeded those living in rural areas for the first time in history. 1<br />

This is a dramatic increase from 1950, when the number <strong>of</strong> people<br />

living in urban areas worldwide was approximately 29%. 2<br />

This<br />

trend is likely to increase exponentially even within the next few<br />

decades. The United Nations’ World Urbanization Prospects report<br />

predicts that that by 2030, at least 60% <strong>of</strong> the global population<br />

(approximately 4.9 billion) will live in urban areas and that by<br />

2050, 67% (approximately 6.3 billion) will do so.<br />

There is an uneven distribution, however, in the levels <strong>of</strong> urbanisation<br />

across the world. By 2015, the percentage <strong>of</strong> people living in urban<br />

areas in North America and Europe is expected to hit 83% and 74%<br />

respectively. This is far greater than in Africa or Asia (41% and 48%<br />

respectively). Thus, the proportion <strong>of</strong> the population living in urban<br />

areas in the UK is projected to reach 80%, compared to 56% in<br />

China and 33% in India. Nevertheless, in 2050 the fastest rates <strong>of</strong><br />

urban population growth are expected to be recorded in Africa and<br />

Asia. 3<br />

Between 2015 and 2050, it is estimated that the percentage <strong>of</strong><br />

the population living in urban areas in Africa and Asia will grow by<br />

17%, compared to 5% in North America and 8% in Europe.<br />

Indeed, the greatest changes to the global urban landscape in the<br />

coming decades are likely predominantly to take place in Africa<br />

and Asia. Asia currently has the largest urban population with<br />

around 2 billion people living in urban agglomerations. By 2050,<br />

this is expected to exceed 3.3 billion. Africa, which currently has<br />

one <strong>of</strong> the smallest urban populations, is expected to have the<br />

second largest by 2050. Its urban population is predicted to more<br />

than treble, reaching approximately 1.3 billion people.<br />

1 Source: United Nations, Department <strong>of</strong> Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division, World<br />

Urbanization Prospects: The 2011 Revision. The Population Division <strong>of</strong> the UN’s Department <strong>of</strong> Economic<br />

and Social Affairs has been issuing, every two years since 1988, revised estimates and projections <strong>of</strong><br />

the urban and rural populations <strong>of</strong> all countries in the world and <strong>of</strong> their major urban agglomerations.<br />

2 The principal difficulty when considering the precise change to the urban landscape is how to define<br />

the term ‘urban’. The United Nations Population Division relies upon national statistics institutions to<br />

collect its data, each <strong>of</strong> which differs to an extent in their definitions <strong>of</strong> what constitutes an urban area.<br />

It is important to bear this in mind when drawing comparisons between nations and urban agglomerations.<br />

3 United Nations, Department <strong>of</strong> Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division, World Urbanization<br />

Prospects: The 2010 Revision.


78 Big Picture<br />

CHART 1<br />

Location <strong>of</strong> the world’s megacities and percentage <strong>of</strong> urbanisation – 2010<br />

Percentage<br />

urban<br />

81-100%<br />

61-80%<br />

41-60%<br />

21-40%<br />

0-20% Population sizes <strong>of</strong> megacities<br />

30+ million 25-30 million 20-25 million<br />

15-20 million 10-15 million<br />

Source: United Nations Population Division (http://esa.un.org/unpd/wup/index.htm).<br />

THE RISE OF MEGACITIES<br />

Alongside the increasing phenomenon <strong>of</strong> urbanisation, there has been<br />

a rise both in the number <strong>of</strong> ‘megacities’ in the world – those with<br />

more than 10 million inhabitants – and in the size <strong>of</strong> those cities’<br />

populations. In 1950, there were only two megacities in the world:<br />

New York and Tokyo. Both <strong>of</strong> these cities had populations <strong>of</strong> around<br />

12 million people. By 2010, there were 23 megacities (see Chart 1).<br />

By 2025, this trend is expected to continue, reaching an expected 37<br />

megacities worldwide (Chart 2).<br />

The growth in megacities is mainly a phenomenon <strong>of</strong> the emerging<br />

economies. In 2010, 14 <strong>of</strong> the new megacities born since 1950 were<br />

to be found in either Africa or Asia. More specifically, 17 <strong>of</strong> the new<br />

megacities were located in the BRIC or N-11 4<br />

economies. 5<br />

Similarly,<br />

eight <strong>of</strong> the additional 14 new megacities expected to grow by 2025<br />

are predicted to come from either the BRIC or N-11 economies. If this<br />

comes to pass, these emerging economies will account for 68% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

world’s largest urban agglomerations by 2025.<br />

THE WORLD’S LARGEST<br />

EMERGING MEGACITIES<br />

In 2010, Tokyo was the world’s largest megacity with a population<br />

size <strong>of</strong> approximately 36 million, and is predicted to remain the<br />

world’s largest urban agglomeration by 2025. The BRIC economies,<br />

led principally by China and India, are expected to produce some <strong>of</strong><br />

4 The N-11, or ‘Next 11’, economies are the 11 countries – Bangladesh, Egypt, Indonesia, Iran, Mexico,<br />

Nigeria, Pakistan, Philippines, Turkey, South Korea and Vietnam – identified in 2005 by Goldman Sachs as<br />

having a high potential <strong>of</strong> becoming, along with the BRICs, the world’s largest economies in the 21st<br />

century.<br />

5 Source: Goldman Sachs, Global Economics Paper No:134.


CHART 2<br />

Future cities – the survival <strong>of</strong> the fastest 79<br />

Location <strong>of</strong> the world’s megacities and percentage <strong>of</strong> urbanisation – 2025<br />

Percentage<br />

urban<br />

81-100%<br />

61-80%<br />

41-60%<br />

21-40%<br />

0-20% Population sizes <strong>of</strong> megacities<br />

30+ million 25-30 million 20-25 million<br />

15-20 million 10-15 million<br />

Source: United Nations Population Division (http://esa.un.org/unpd/wup/index.htm).<br />

the next largest. India’s megacities <strong>of</strong> New Delhi and Mumbai are<br />

predicted respectively to be the second and fourth largest megacities<br />

in the world, with populations exceeding 25 million people.<br />

In 2010, China had four megacities, with two, Shanghai and Beijing,<br />

being in the top ten by size <strong>of</strong> population, both with in excess <strong>of</strong> 15<br />

million inhabitants. By 2025, it is predicted that China will have seven<br />

megacities – all <strong>of</strong> which will have populations exceeding 11 million,<br />

with Shanghai and Beijing exceeding 22 million. 6<br />

China will have<br />

more megacities than any other country in the world.<br />

The world’s emerging economies have therefore driven much <strong>of</strong> the<br />

change in the rankings <strong>of</strong> the largest urban agglomerations. With the<br />

exception <strong>of</strong> Japan, the more developed nations have fallen behind.<br />

New York has dropped from being the world’s largest urban<br />

agglomeration in 1950, to being the fourth largest in 2010, and is<br />

expected to fall still further by 2025.<br />

THE FASTEST GROWING<br />

MEGACITIES, 2015–2025<br />

The top dozen fastest growing megacities between 2015 and 2025<br />

will be located in either Africa or Asia. Lagos, Nigeria, is expected to<br />

be the fastest growing megacity with growth <strong>of</strong> 75% between 2010<br />

and 2025 (see Chart 3). Four out <strong>of</strong> the top five cities predicted to<br />

grow most quickly between 2015 and 2025 are from the N-11<br />

economies. Kinshasa in the Democratic Republic <strong>of</strong> Congo is predicted<br />

to be the second fastest growing megacity, with an expected<br />

6 The Chinese government has plans to merge the nine cities surrounding the Pearl River Delta, which<br />

include the cities <strong>of</strong> Shenzhen and Guangzhou-Guangdong, to make one megacity <strong>of</strong> approximately 42<br />

million people. It is unclear, however, how long this process will take or whether the UN will consider this<br />

as a single megacity or as a conglomeration <strong>of</strong> several megacities. As such it has not been considered as<br />

a single megacity for the purposes <strong>of</strong> this article.


80 Big Picture<br />

CHART 3<br />

Expected population growth rate <strong>of</strong> megacities 2015-2025<br />

Lagos<br />

Kinshasa<br />

Bangalore<br />

Hyderabad<br />

Dhaka<br />

Lahore<br />

Shenzhen<br />

Beijing<br />

Chennai<br />

Delhi<br />

Karachi<br />

Guangzhou<br />

Shanghai<br />

Wuhan<br />

Chongqing<br />

Tianjin<br />

Manila<br />

Bangkok<br />

Mumbai<br />

Istanbul<br />

Bogotá<br />

Cairo<br />

Jakarta<br />

Kolkata<br />

Lima<br />

Mexico City<br />

Chicago<br />

Los Angeles<br />

Sao Paulo<br />

New York<br />

Buenos Aires<br />

Paris<br />

London<br />

Rio de Janeiro<br />

Moscow<br />

Osaka-Kobe<br />

Tokyo<br />

0<br />

10 20 30 40<br />

% Growth Rate<br />

50 60 70 80<br />

Source: UN Department <strong>of</strong> Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division, World Urbanization Prospects 2011.<br />

population growth <strong>of</strong> 73%. Bangalore and Hyderabad in India are<br />

projected to increase in size by 59% and 54% respectively, with Dhaka<br />

in Bangladesh close behind (53%).<br />

The megacities predicted to show the slowest growth are primarily<br />

those located in developed nations. London, for example, is ‘only’<br />

expected to grow by 15% between 2015 and 2025. The population<br />

<strong>of</strong> Tokyo, despite remaining the world’s largest urban agglomeration,<br />

is projected to increase by 4.7%. By the standards <strong>of</strong> their<br />

counterparts in the BRIC and N-11 economies, the growth <strong>of</strong> these<br />

megacities looks positively sluggish in comparison, as the chart above<br />

illustrates.


“The megacities<br />

predicted to show the<br />

slowest growth are<br />

primarily those<br />

located in developed<br />

nations.”<br />

Future cities – the survival <strong>of</strong> the fastest 81<br />

WHAT ABOUT SMALLER CITIES?<br />

Megacities will play a crucial role in the future global urban landscape.<br />

However, most (52%) <strong>of</strong> the globe’s urban dwellers currently live in<br />

cities <strong>of</strong> fewer than 500,000 people. Even by 2025, megacities will<br />

only account for approximately 10% <strong>of</strong> the world’s urban population.<br />

Between 2010 and 2025, it is expected that around 45% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

increase in urban dwellers will be accounted for by small cities <strong>of</strong><br />

fewer than 500,000 people.<br />

WHAT’S DRIVING INCREASING<br />

URBANISATION?<br />

Three major factors are shaping the global urban landscape, varying in<br />

importance between urban agglomerations. The first is the result <strong>of</strong><br />

natural population growth and changing demographics within urban<br />

areas. Many <strong>of</strong> the emerging economies, for example, are<br />

experiencing increased rates <strong>of</strong> life expectancy, whilst still maintaining<br />

relatively high birth rates.<br />

The second factor is rural-urban migration, or ‘rural flight’, with the<br />

socio-economic benefits that cities <strong>of</strong>fer acting as a strong pull factor<br />

for those living in rural areas. This was previously held as the principal<br />

factor influencing urbanisation rates, 7<br />

and, whilst that is now debated,<br />

by 2050 it is nevertheless predicted that only five countries in the<br />

world will have rural populations that are not in decline. 8<br />

The third factor is the blurring over time <strong>of</strong> the boundaries between<br />

urban and rural areas, particularly due to the growth in transportation<br />

and communication networks. As cities expand, they <strong>of</strong>ten merge<br />

with other districts and urban areas, increasing the size <strong>of</strong> the urban<br />

population artificially. All three factors have contributed towards<br />

global urban growth, though they clearly vary in importance and<br />

relevance between different cities.<br />

THE EFFECTS OF GLOBALISATION<br />

Cities are now more globally integrated than at any other time in<br />

history. Globalisation can be overwhelmingly positive for the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> an urban agglomeration: the integration <strong>of</strong> global<br />

economies can expand market opportunities and lead to the growth<br />

and influx <strong>of</strong> technological and managerial expertise, resulting in<br />

greater opportunities for wealth creation. Conversely, though, the<br />

integration <strong>of</strong> global economies has meant that urban agglomerations<br />

are more susceptible to external market shocks. This was particularly<br />

evident in the global recession <strong>of</strong> 2008. As most economic activity<br />

takes place in cities, urban dwellers are more exposed to the effects <strong>of</strong><br />

economic fluctuations, <strong>of</strong>ten resulting in a loss <strong>of</strong> job opportunities<br />

and investment. Cities are very much at the mercy <strong>of</strong> the global<br />

economy, and will continue to be so.<br />

Clearly globalisation and urbanisation are about more than just<br />

people. Many fast-growing emerging economy cities will remain far<br />

7 Somik V. Lall, Harris Selod & Zmarak Shalizi, Rural-Urban Migration in Developing Countries, World Bank Policy<br />

Research Working Paper 3915, World Bank Group, May 2006.<br />

8 United Nations, Department <strong>of</strong> Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division, World Urbanization Prospects:<br />

The 2011 Revision.


82 Big Picture<br />

“Many fast-growing<br />

emerging economy<br />

cities will remain far<br />

poorer than slowergrowing<br />

advanced<br />

economy cities.”<br />

poorer than slower-growing advanced economy cities. What<br />

ultimately matters for businesses is the size and growth <strong>of</strong> the urban<br />

economies.<br />

Table 1 shows the 50 most dynamic cities in the world, according to<br />

the McKinsey Global <strong>Institute</strong> Cityscope database. The dynamism<br />

measure shows the $ billion increase in the size <strong>of</strong> these urban<br />

economies over the 2010–2025 period, together with the percentage<br />

change in growth.<br />

Table 1 shows that:<br />

o The 10 largest urban economies in the world in 2025 will still be<br />

dominated by advanced economies. According to McKinsey, in<br />

rank order they will be Tokyo, New York, Shanghai, Los Angeles,<br />

Beijing, London, Paris, São Paulo, Moscow and Chicago.<br />

o Emerging economies such as China will dominate dollar growth<br />

in urban economies over the 2010-2025 period.<br />

THE ‘AEROTROPOLIS’<br />

The term ‘aerotropolis’ was first coined by John D. Kasarda from the<br />

University <strong>of</strong> North Carolina’s Kenan-Flagler Business School. 9<br />

Kasarda’s<br />

vision is that airports will dictate future cities and urban landscapes. In<br />

order for cities to compete and thrive, he believes, airports can no<br />

longer be situated on the periphery connected by inadequate<br />

transport links. The most efficient cities will be those that have the<br />

airport in their centre and have established other communication and<br />

transport networks that serve to intertwine the city with the airport so<br />

that, in effect, the airport becomes the city.<br />

In other words, the airport is not only in the aviation business but also in<br />

real estate and urban planning. Underpinning the aerotropolis idea is<br />

that in order for cities and districts to remain competitive, they need to<br />

be able to maintain their position as innovators and producers. To ensure<br />

this, they need the ability to move people, goods and ideas as quickly<br />

and efficiently as possible through the value chain. According to Kasarda,<br />

this can only be delivered by state-<strong>of</strong>-the-art connectivity by broadband<br />

and air transportation. The aerotropolis is therefore not just an airport at<br />

the centre <strong>of</strong> a city, but a city that serves this vision <strong>of</strong> efficiency:<br />

“It is the way you reduce time, the way you reduce costs, the way you<br />

reduce speed...it is where the elastic mile, the friction <strong>of</strong> space, community<br />

without propinquity, and trade routes all come together.”<br />

The megacities <strong>of</strong> the world aren’t competing against their rural<br />

districts or other smaller cities within close proximity. Rather they are<br />

competing against other world megacities. It is less the survival <strong>of</strong> the<br />

fittest, more the survival <strong>of</strong> the fastest. The most important issue is<br />

speed and proximity to market. Cities that have the greatest<br />

connectivity and provide a platform for greater speed in relation to<br />

the supply chain are going to be the most competitive. This helps to<br />

explain why, despite being 7,000 miles apart, Las Vegas and Macau<br />

are competing to become the gambling capital <strong>of</strong> the world.<br />

Companies aren’t competing against one another; it is their supply<br />

9 Kasarda, J. D., and Lindsay, G., Aerotropolis. The way we’ll live next, Farrar, Straus and Girroux, 2011.


TABLE 1<br />

Rank<br />

1<br />

2<br />

3<br />

4<br />

5<br />

6<br />

7<br />

8<br />

9<br />

10<br />

11<br />

12<br />

13<br />

14<br />

15<br />

16<br />

17<br />

18<br />

19<br />

20<br />

21<br />

22<br />

23<br />

24<br />

25<br />

26<br />

27<br />

28<br />

29<br />

30<br />

31<br />

32<br />

33<br />

34<br />

35<br />

36<br />

37<br />

38<br />

39<br />

40<br />

41<br />

42<br />

43<br />

44<br />

45<br />

46<br />

47<br />

48<br />

49<br />

50<br />

City<br />

Shanghai<br />

Beijing<br />

Tianjin<br />

São Paulo<br />

Guangzhou<br />

Shenzhen<br />

New York<br />

Chongquin<br />

Moscow<br />

Tokyo<br />

Wuhan<br />

Los Angeles<br />

Foshan<br />

Istanbul<br />

Nanjing<br />

Chengdu<br />

Hangzhou<br />

Dongguan<br />

Singapore<br />

Shenyang<br />

London<br />

Houston<br />

Dallas<br />

Xian<br />

Washington<br />

Paris<br />

Suzhou<br />

Mexico City<br />

Riyadh<br />

Hong Kong<br />

Bangkok<br />

Buenos Aires<br />

Doha<br />

Rio de Janeiro<br />

Dalian<br />

Wuxi<br />

Seoul<br />

Chicago<br />

Delhi<br />

Ningbo<br />

Jinan<br />

Xiamen<br />

Jakarta<br />

Miami<br />

Kuwait City<br />

Qingdao<br />

Sydney<br />

Atlanta<br />

Brasilia<br />

Taipei<br />

Country<br />

China<br />

China<br />

China<br />

Brazil<br />

China<br />

China<br />

US<br />

China<br />

Russia<br />

Japan<br />

China<br />

US<br />

China<br />

Turkey<br />

China<br />

China<br />

China<br />

China<br />

Singapore<br />

China<br />

UK<br />

US<br />

US<br />

China<br />

US<br />

France<br />

China<br />

Mexico<br />

Saudi Arabia<br />

China<br />

T<strong>hail</strong>and<br />

Argentina<br />

Qatar<br />

Brazil<br />

China<br />

China<br />

South Korea<br />

US<br />

India<br />

China<br />

China<br />

China<br />

Indonesia<br />

US<br />

Kuwait<br />

China<br />

Australia<br />

US<br />

Brazil<br />

Taiwan<br />

% growth<br />

344%<br />

398%<br />

385%<br />

109%<br />

292%<br />

270%<br />

32%<br />

418%<br />

111%<br />

18%<br />

404%<br />

44%<br />

360%<br />

155%<br />

402%<br />

435%<br />

335%<br />

375%<br />

104%<br />

346%<br />

29%<br />

64%<br />

67%<br />

523%<br />

53%<br />

27%<br />

389%<br />

80%<br />

165%<br />

89%<br />

185%<br />

100%<br />

179%<br />

97%<br />

319%<br />

362%<br />

72%<br />

33%<br />

344%<br />

358%<br />

348%<br />

491%<br />

209%<br />

61%<br />

123%<br />

295%<br />

53%<br />

57%<br />

139%<br />

88%<br />

Total growth<br />

($bn)<br />

861.5<br />

821.7<br />

495.7<br />

475.7<br />

426.9<br />

382.1<br />

372.7<br />

370.0<br />

362.7<br />

343.9<br />

332.2<br />

319.7<br />

300.1<br />

291.5<br />

275.4<br />

251.7<br />

236.5<br />

235.5<br />

231.4<br />

222.5<br />

221.1<br />

218.8<br />

216.3<br />

212.6<br />

207.5<br />

207.2<br />

204.8<br />

204.4<br />

202.9<br />

199.1<br />

194.6<br />

192.6<br />

176.3<br />

175.2<br />

171.9<br />

170.2<br />

167.0<br />

165.0<br />

163.9<br />

160.8<br />

150.2<br />

149.3<br />

147.7<br />

144.34<br />

144.33<br />

142.0<br />

141.8<br />

141.7<br />

141.03<br />

141.0<br />

Population (m)<br />

22.3<br />

18.8<br />

11.1<br />

19.7<br />

11.1<br />

10.4<br />

18.9<br />

15.7<br />

11.6<br />

36.4<br />

9.8<br />

12.9<br />

7.2<br />

11.0<br />

7.2<br />

7.7<br />

6.2<br />

8.2<br />

5.1<br />

6.1<br />

14.9<br />

6.0<br />

6.4<br />

6.5<br />

5.6<br />

11.8<br />

4.1<br />

20.1<br />

5.2<br />

7.1<br />

6.9<br />

13.1<br />

1.3<br />

11.8<br />

3.9<br />

3.5<br />

9.8<br />

9.5<br />

16.3<br />

3.5<br />

3.4<br />

3.5<br />

9.6<br />

5.6<br />

2.3<br />

3.7<br />

4.6<br />

5.3<br />

3.7<br />

6.8<br />

30.9<br />

29.6<br />

15.2<br />

23.2<br />

14.9<br />

13.7<br />

19.7<br />

19.4<br />

12.7<br />

36.7<br />

13.1<br />

15.0<br />

10.8<br />

14.9<br />

9.9<br />

11.2<br />

8.8<br />

11.4<br />

5.8<br />

8.4<br />

16.2<br />

7.7<br />

8.6<br />

9.1<br />

6.6<br />

12.9<br />

6.5<br />

21.6<br />

8.1<br />

8.2<br />

9.4<br />

15.2<br />

1.6<br />

13.6<br />

5.7<br />

5.4<br />

9.5<br />

10.2<br />

21.4<br />

5.1<br />

5.7<br />

5.3<br />

12.8<br />

7.2<br />

3.2<br />

5.1<br />

5.8<br />

6.8<br />

5.0<br />

6.9<br />

50 dynamic cities<br />

2010 2025 2010 2025<br />

GDP ($bn)<br />

250.7<br />

206.2<br />

128.8<br />

437.3<br />

146.1<br />

141.5<br />

1,180.3<br />

88.6<br />

325.8<br />

1,874.7<br />

82.2<br />

731.8<br />

83.5<br />

188.2<br />

68.5<br />

57.8<br />

70.5<br />

62.7<br />

222.7<br />

64.3<br />

751.8<br />

341.1<br />

324.9<br />

40.6<br />

392.2<br />

764.2<br />

52.7<br />

255.1<br />

122.7<br />

224.5<br />

105.0<br />

191.7<br />

98.8<br />

180.9<br />

53.8<br />

47.0<br />

233.3<br />

496.4<br />

47.6<br />

45.0<br />

43.2<br />

30.4<br />

70.7<br />

235.9<br />

117.5<br />

48.1<br />

268.9<br />

249.7<br />

101.6<br />

160.3<br />

1,112.2<br />

1,027.9<br />

624.4<br />

912.9<br />

573.0<br />

523.6<br />

1,553.1<br />

458.6<br />

688.5<br />

2,218.6<br />

414.4<br />

1,051.5<br />

383.6<br />

479.7<br />

343.9<br />

309.6<br />

307.0<br />

297.9<br />

454.1<br />

286.9<br />

972.9<br />

559.9<br />

541.2<br />

253.3<br />

599.7<br />

971.4<br />

257.5<br />

459.5<br />

325.6<br />

423.6<br />

299.6<br />

384.3<br />

275.1<br />

356.1<br />

225.7<br />

217.2<br />

400.3<br />

661.4<br />

211.4<br />

205.7<br />

193.4<br />

179.8<br />

218.4<br />

380.2<br />

261.8<br />

190.1<br />

410.6<br />

391.4<br />

242.6<br />

301.3<br />

Source: ‘The Cities Issue’, Foreign Policy magazine, September-October 2012.<br />

Future cities – the survival <strong>of</strong> the fastest 83


84 Big Picture<br />

chains that are competing. It is the supply chain that creates true<br />

competitive advantage by securing the best resources and delivering<br />

them quickly and efficiently to market. It is the airport that guarantees<br />

this vision and acts efficiently to serve the needs <strong>of</strong> the market. Whilst<br />

the Internet has helped create this phenomenon, it couldn’t happen<br />

without the airport. According to Kasarda, air travel has become the<br />

physical Internet, moving goods and services around the globe as<br />

efficiently and effectively as the Internet itself.<br />

THE IMPLICATIONS FOR THE UK<br />

The aerotropolis idea has already had a significant impact on the<br />

future urban landscape. China has the largest number <strong>of</strong> megacities in<br />

the world and some <strong>of</strong> those cities have grown substantially in<br />

accordance with the aerotropolis model. The reason that China’s<br />

megacities have grown so big, so quickly is due in substantial part to<br />

the cheap transportation spawned by the jet engine, and the<br />

attendant increase in access to foreign markets. 10<br />

The Pearl River Delta,<br />

the ‘factory <strong>of</strong> the world’, has been successful because it has<br />

concentrated production around air transit. China has understood the<br />

strategic importance <strong>of</strong> the aerotropolis and plans to build 100 new<br />

airports by 2020. The implications for the UK are obvious. A debate<br />

about a new short runway at Heathrow hardly satisfies the strategic<br />

vision within the aerotropolis concept. If the concept is valid, then<br />

bolder initiatives need to be considered, such as ‘Boris Island’, the Isle<br />

<strong>of</strong> Grain proposals advanced by Foster, or a three or four-runway<br />

Heathrow.<br />

Emerging economies such as China are not just catching up with the<br />

advanced economies. In many instances they are leading the change<br />

10 World Bank Group, World Development Report 2009: Reshaping Economic Geography.


“We are moving into a<br />

world characterised by<br />

connectivity and the<br />

survival <strong>of</strong> the fastest,<br />

via the Internet and<br />

transport networks.”<br />

Future cities – the survival <strong>of</strong> the fastest 85<br />

in urbanisation and transport systems because they have no<br />

alternative, due to the high levels <strong>of</strong> congestion and pollution they are<br />

experiencing.<br />

China already has the world’s largest car market, with the number <strong>of</strong><br />

vehicles projected to explode from 200 to 600 million by 2030.<br />

Annual car purchases are projected to jump from 14.5 million to 50<br />

million by 2020. The dire congestion and pollution implications are<br />

forcing infrastructure investment and innovation, with the Chinese<br />

spending $500 billion (9% <strong>of</strong> GDP) on infrastructure, albeit not always<br />

in the most efficient way. However, new and innovative approaches to<br />

urbanisation and transport are evident, which display the vision,<br />

determination and implementation we need in the UK:<br />

o Over the past five years the Chinese have constructed 20,000<br />

miles <strong>of</strong> expressway.<br />

o China’s latest bullet trains travel at more than 300 miles per hour.<br />

o The Chinese are investigating next generation ‘maglev’-style<br />

trains, which could travel at up to 600 miles per hour.<br />

o Over the next three years China plans to build 70 new airports,<br />

including a new mega-airport in Beijing, with double the<br />

passenger capacity <strong>of</strong> Atlanta – currently the world’s busiest airport.<br />

o The Chinese firm Broad Group has pioneered new modular<br />

construction techniques, which promise to build a 220-story<br />

skyscraper in just 90 days in Changsha. This building will be<br />

taller than the 160-story Burj Khalifa in Dubai, which took six<br />

years to complete.<br />

We are moving into a world characterised by connectivity and the<br />

survival <strong>of</strong> the fastest, via the Internet and transport networks. The UK<br />

cannot afford to languish in the slow lane.<br />

São Paulo, Brazil


IoD CONTACTS & CREDITS<br />

Kathryn Allix<br />

Deputy Office Manager, Policy Unit 020 7451 3289 kathryn.allix@iod.com<br />

Dr. Roger Barker<br />

Head <strong>of</strong> Corporate Governance 020 7451 3344 roger.barker@iod.com<br />

Richard Baron<br />

Head <strong>of</strong> Taxation 020 7451 3212 richard.baron@iod.com<br />

Alexander Ehmann<br />

Head <strong>of</strong> Government and Parliamentary Affairs 020 7451 3284 alexander.ehmann@iod.com<br />

Ingrid Farmer<br />

Policy Unit Manager 020 7451 3280 ingrid.farmer@iod.com<br />

Mike Harris<br />

Head <strong>of</strong> Policy Development 020 7451 3285 mike.harris@iod.com<br />

Graeme Leach<br />

Chief Economist and Director <strong>of</strong> Policy 020 7451 3366 graeme.leach@iod.com<br />

Dan Lewis<br />

Senior Adviser, Energy Policy 020 7451 3103 dan.lewis@iod.com<br />

Edwin Morgan<br />

Media Relations Manager 020 7451 3392 edwin.morgan@iod.com<br />

Philip Sack<br />

Senior Adviser, Employment Policy 020 7451 3103 philip.sack@iod.com<br />

Malcolm Small<br />

Senior Adviser, Pensions Policy 020 7451 3134 malcolm.small@iod.com<br />

Corin Taylor<br />

Senior Economic Adviser 020 7451 3282 corin.taylor@iod.com<br />

Mark Wallace<br />

Head <strong>of</strong> Media Relations 020 7451 3263 mark.wallace@iod.com<br />

For subscription information and all general enquiries about Big Picture, contact Kathryn Allix.<br />

Printed and bound in Great Britain by Newnorth Print Ltd.


Inspiring Leaders.<br />

Supporting Business.<br />

The <strong>Institute</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Directors</strong> has been inspiring leaders and supporting business since 1903. Our<br />

members come from across the business spectrum. From entrepreneurial start-ups to<br />

directors <strong>of</strong> charities and CEOs <strong>of</strong> multinational corporations, all are leaders in their field.<br />

Our experience means that we understand business and its complexities and know the<br />

diverse demands placed on you as a leader. That’s why we’ve designed membership to provide<br />

a range <strong>of</strong> tangible benefits that <strong>of</strong>fer support in the day-to-day demands <strong>of</strong> your role, making<br />

working life easier.<br />

THE BENEFITS OF IoD MEMBERSHIP<br />

• Free access to IoD meeting space;<br />

• Local networking events across the UK;<br />

• Free one-to-one business advice;<br />

• National conferences, seminars and events;<br />

• Pr<strong>of</strong>essional development courses for directors by directors;<br />

• Free business information and research;<br />

• Free business tax and legal advice;<br />

• Your views represented to government.<br />

Not a member <strong>of</strong> the IoD?<br />

To join today or to find out more, call a member <strong>of</strong> our team on<br />

020 7766 8888 and quote BP012A, or visit www.iod.com/benefits.


<strong>Institute</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Directors</strong><br />

116 Pall Mall, London SW1Y 5ED<br />

www.iod.com

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!