14.01.2013 Views

essays in public finance and industrial organization a dissertation ...

essays in public finance and industrial organization a dissertation ...

essays in public finance and industrial organization a dissertation ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

ESSAYS IN PUBLIC FINANCE<br />

AND<br />

INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION<br />

A DISSERTATION<br />

SUBMITTED TO THE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS<br />

AND THE COMMITTEE ON GRADUATE STUDIES<br />

OF STANFORD UNIVERSITY<br />

IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS<br />

FOR THE DEGREE OF<br />

DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY<br />

Neale Mahoney<br />

May 2011


© 2011 by Neale Ashok Mahoney. All Rights Reserved.<br />

Re-distributed by Stanford University under license with the author.<br />

This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-<br />

Noncommercial 3.0 United States License.<br />

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/3.0/us/<br />

This <strong>dissertation</strong> is onl<strong>in</strong>e at: http://purl.stanford.edu/fx992pz6459<br />

ii


I certify that I have read this <strong>dissertation</strong> <strong>and</strong> that, <strong>in</strong> my op<strong>in</strong>ion, it is fully adequate<br />

<strong>in</strong> scope <strong>and</strong> quality as a <strong>dissertation</strong> for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.<br />

Jonathan Lev<strong>in</strong>, Primary Adviser<br />

I certify that I have read this <strong>dissertation</strong> <strong>and</strong> that, <strong>in</strong> my op<strong>in</strong>ion, it is fully adequate<br />

<strong>in</strong> scope <strong>and</strong> quality as a <strong>dissertation</strong> for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.<br />

Liran E<strong>in</strong>av<br />

I certify that I have read this <strong>dissertation</strong> <strong>and</strong> that, <strong>in</strong> my op<strong>in</strong>ion, it is fully adequate<br />

<strong>in</strong> scope <strong>and</strong> quality as a <strong>dissertation</strong> for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.<br />

Approved for the Stanford University Committee on Graduate Studies.<br />

Carol<strong>in</strong>e Hoxby<br />

Patricia J. Gumport, Vice Provost Graduate Education<br />

This signature page was generated electronically upon submission of this <strong>dissertation</strong> <strong>in</strong><br />

electronic format. An orig<strong>in</strong>al signed hard copy of the signature page is on file <strong>in</strong><br />

University Archives.<br />

iii


Preface<br />

This <strong>dissertation</strong> has four chapters. The first three chapters exam<strong>in</strong>e health <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

markets <strong>in</strong> the U.S., focus<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> particular on contexts where there are important<br />

<strong>in</strong>teractions between health <strong>in</strong>surance plans. The fourth chapter is on the U.S. budget,<br />

exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the implications of annual budget cycles on the quantity <strong>and</strong> quality of<br />

end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Chapter 1, entitled “Bankruptcy as Implicit Health Insurance” exam<strong>in</strong>es the <strong>in</strong>ter-<br />

action between health <strong>in</strong>surance <strong>and</strong> the implicit <strong>in</strong>surance that people have because<br />

they can file (or threaten to file) for bankruptcy. With a simple model that captures<br />

key <strong>in</strong>stitutional features, I demonstrate that the f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk from medical shocks<br />

is capped by the assets that could be seized <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy. For households with mod-<br />

est seizable assets, this implicit “bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance” can crowd out conventional<br />

health <strong>in</strong>surance. I test these predictions us<strong>in</strong>g variation <strong>in</strong> the state laws that specify<br />

the type <strong>and</strong> level of assets that can be seized <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy. Because of the differ<strong>in</strong>g<br />

laws, people who have the same assets <strong>and</strong> receive the same medical care face different<br />

losses <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy. Exploit<strong>in</strong>g the variation <strong>in</strong> seizable assets that is orthogonal to<br />

wealth <strong>and</strong> other household characteristics, I show that households with fewer seiz-<br />

able assets are more likely to be un<strong>in</strong>sured. This f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g is consistent with another:<br />

un<strong>in</strong>sured households with fewer seizable assets end up mak<strong>in</strong>g lower out-of-pocket<br />

medical payments. The estimates suggest that if the laws of the least debtor-friendly<br />

state of Delaware were applied nationally, 16.3 percent of the un<strong>in</strong>sured would buy<br />

health <strong>in</strong>surance. Achiev<strong>in</strong>g the same <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> coverage would require a premium<br />

subsidy of approximately 44.0 percent. To shed light on puzzles <strong>in</strong> the literature <strong>and</strong><br />

exam<strong>in</strong>e policy counterfactuals, I calibrate a utility-based, micro-simulation model of<br />

iv


<strong>in</strong>surance choice. Among other th<strong>in</strong>gs, simulations show that “bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance”<br />

expla<strong>in</strong>s the low take-up of high-deductible health <strong>in</strong>surance.<br />

Chapter 2, entitled “Pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Welfare <strong>in</strong> Health Plan Choice”, is coauthored<br />

with M. Kate Bundorf <strong>and</strong> Jonathan Lev<strong>in</strong>. The start<strong>in</strong>g po<strong>in</strong>t for the paper is the<br />

simple observation that when <strong>in</strong>surance premiums do not reflect <strong>in</strong>dividual differences<br />

<strong>in</strong> expected costs, consumers may choose plans <strong>in</strong>efficiently. We study this problem <strong>in</strong><br />

health <strong>in</strong>surance markets, a sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> which prices often do not <strong>in</strong>corporate observable<br />

differences <strong>in</strong> expected costs. We develop a simple model <strong>and</strong> estimate it us<strong>in</strong>g data<br />

on small employers. In this sett<strong>in</strong>g, the welfare loss compared to the feasible risk-<br />

rated benchmark is around 2-11% of coverage costs. Three-quarters of this is due<br />

to restrictions on risk-rat<strong>in</strong>g employee contributions; the rest is due to <strong>in</strong>efficient<br />

contribution choices. Despite the <strong>in</strong>efficiency, the benefits from plan choice relative<br />

to each of the s<strong>in</strong>gle-plan options are substantial.<br />

Chapter 3, entitled “The Private Coverage <strong>and</strong> Public Costs: Identify<strong>in</strong>g the Effect<br />

of Private Supplemental Insurance on Medicare Spend<strong>in</strong>g,” is coauthored with Marika<br />

Cabral. While most elderly Americans have health <strong>in</strong>surance coverage through Medi-<br />

care, traditional Medicare policies leave <strong>in</strong>dividuals exposed to significant f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

risk. Private supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance to “fill the gaps” of Medicare, known as Medi-<br />

gap, is very popular. In this Chapter, we estimate the impact of this supplemental<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance on total medical spend<strong>in</strong>g us<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>strumental variables strategy that<br />

leverages discont<strong>in</strong>uities <strong>in</strong> Medigap premiums at state boundaries. Our estimates<br />

suggest that Medigap <strong>in</strong>creases medical spend<strong>in</strong>g by 57 percent—or about 40 percent<br />

more than previous estimates. Back-of-the-envelope calculations <strong>in</strong>dicate that a 20<br />

percent tax on premiums would generate comb<strong>in</strong>ed revenue <strong>and</strong> sav<strong>in</strong>gs of 6.2 percent<br />

of basel<strong>in</strong>e costs; a Pigovian tax that fully accounts for the fiscal externality would<br />

yield sav<strong>in</strong>gs of 18.1 percent.<br />

Chapter 4, entitled “Do Expir<strong>in</strong>g Budgets Lead to Wasteful Year-End Spend<strong>in</strong>g?<br />

Evidence from Federal Procurement,” is coauthored with Jeffrey Liebman. Many<br />

<strong>organization</strong>s fund their spend<strong>in</strong>g out of a fixed budget that expires at year’s end.<br />

Faced with uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty over future spend<strong>in</strong>g dem<strong>and</strong>s, these <strong>organization</strong>s have an<br />

<strong>in</strong>centive to build a buffer stock of funds over the front end of the budget cycle.<br />

v


When dem<strong>and</strong> does not materialize, they then rush to spend these funds on lower<br />

quality projects at the end of the year. We test these predictions us<strong>in</strong>g data on<br />

procurement spend<strong>in</strong>g by the U.S. federal government. Us<strong>in</strong>g data on all federal<br />

contracts from 2004 through 2009, we document that spend<strong>in</strong>g spikes <strong>in</strong> all major<br />

federal agencies dur<strong>in</strong>g the 52nd week of the year as the agencies rush to exhaust<br />

expir<strong>in</strong>g budget authority. Spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the last week of the year is 4.9 times higher<br />

than the rest-of-the-year weekly average. We exam<strong>in</strong>e the relative quality of year-end<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g us<strong>in</strong>g a newly available dataset that tracks the quality of $130 billion <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>formation technology (I.T.) projects made by federal agencies. Consistent with the<br />

model, average project quality falls at the end of the year. Quality scores <strong>in</strong> the last<br />

week of the year are 2.2 to 5.6 times more likely to be below the central value. To<br />

explore the impact of allow<strong>in</strong>g agencies to roll unused spend<strong>in</strong>g over <strong>in</strong>to subsequent<br />

fiscal years, we study the I.T. contracts of an agency with special authority to roll<br />

over unused fund<strong>in</strong>g. We show that there is only a small end-of-year I.T. spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

spike <strong>in</strong> this agency <strong>and</strong> that the one major I.T. contract this agency issued <strong>in</strong> the<br />

52nd week of the year has a quality rat<strong>in</strong>g that is well above average.<br />

vi


Acknowledgements<br />

I am deeply thankful to my <strong>dissertation</strong> committee for their advice <strong>and</strong> support. I<br />

thank Jonathan Lev<strong>in</strong> for his mentorship. I could not ask for a better adviser or role<br />

model. I thank Carol<strong>in</strong>e Hoxby <strong>and</strong> Liran E<strong>in</strong>av for their exceptional guidance. They<br />

say that your graduate advisers are your advisers for life. Hav<strong>in</strong>g these advisers for<br />

my years at Stanford is already more than I deserve.<br />

I am also grateful to the many faculty members who provided valuable comments<br />

<strong>and</strong> suggestions for my research dur<strong>in</strong>g my graduate studies. Among them are Ran<br />

Abramitzky, Doug Bernheim, Jay Bhattacharya, Nick Bloom, Tim Bresnahan, Kate<br />

Bundorf, Jacub Kastl, <strong>and</strong> Jeffrey Leibman. I thank Kyna Fong for jo<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g my oral<br />

exam committee.<br />

I acknowledge the Ric Weil<strong>and</strong> Graduate Fellowship, Kapnick Fellowship, <strong>and</strong><br />

Shultz Scholarship for f<strong>in</strong>ancial support.<br />

My time at Stanford has been a case study <strong>in</strong> the virtuous cycle of positive peer<br />

effects. I thank Albert Bollard <strong>and</strong> Max Floetotto for their friendship. I am lucky to<br />

have had Aaron Bodoh-Creed, Marika Cabral, Alex Hirsch, Carlos Lever, Marcello<br />

Miccoli, Izi S<strong>in</strong>, <strong>and</strong> Gui Woolston as colleagues <strong>and</strong> friends. I thank Aless<strong>and</strong>ra<br />

Voena most of all.<br />

I am also grateful to my advisers at Brown University for <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g me to the<br />

practice of economic research. I thank Herschel Grossman for countless hours of<br />

debate <strong>and</strong> discussion <strong>and</strong> Roberto Serrano for his wisdom <strong>in</strong> urg<strong>in</strong>g me to pursue<br />

graduate studies.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, I am immensely thankful to my family, my parents Raymond Mahoney<br />

<strong>and</strong> Nal<strong>in</strong>i Shah-Mahoney <strong>and</strong> my brother Col<strong>in</strong>, for their unconditional love <strong>and</strong><br />

vii


support <strong>and</strong> the abundant happ<strong>in</strong>ess they br<strong>in</strong>g to my life.<br />

viii


Contents<br />

Preface iv<br />

Acknowledgements vii<br />

1 Bankruptcy as Implicit Health Insurance 1<br />

1.1 Introduction ................................ 1<br />

1.2 Bankruptcy as a Form of High-Deductible Health Insurance ..... 6<br />

1.2.1 Institutional Background ..................... 6<br />

1.2.2 A Model of Bankruptcy as High-Deductible Health Insurance . 8<br />

1.3 Data Overview .............................. 11<br />

1.3.1 Asset Exemptions ......................... 12<br />

1.3.2 Seizable Assets .......................... 12<br />

1.3.3 Medical Costs ........................... 14<br />

1.3.4 Insurance Premiums ....................... 15<br />

1.4 Empirical Strategy ............................ 16<br />

1.4.1 Coverage Equation ........................ 16<br />

1.4.2 Costs Equation .......................... 16<br />

1.4.3 Cross-State Variation ....................... 17<br />

1.4.4 Historical Homestead Exemptions ................ 19<br />

1.5 The Effect on Insurance Coverage .................... 21<br />

1.5.1 First Stage Estimates ....................... 21<br />

1.5.2 Basel<strong>in</strong>e Coverage Estimates ................... 22<br />

1.5.3 Sensitivity Analysis ........................ 23<br />

ix


1.5.4 Heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> the Effect on Coverage ............ 24<br />

1.5.5 The Effect on Wealth <strong>and</strong> Premiums .............. 25<br />

1.5.6 Summary <strong>and</strong> Interpretation ................... 26<br />

1.6 The Effect on Costs ............................ 27<br />

1.6.1 Basel<strong>in</strong>e Estimates ........................ 27<br />

1.6.2 Sensitivity Analysis ........................ 28<br />

1.6.3 Summary <strong>and</strong> Interpretation ................... 29<br />

1.7 Micro-Simulation Model ......................... 29<br />

1.8 Puzzles <strong>and</strong> Policy ............................ 31<br />

1.8.1 Puzzles ............................... 31<br />

1.8.2 Policy Implications ........................ 33<br />

1.9 Conclusion ................................. 35<br />

1.10 Appendix to Chapter 1 .......................... 36<br />

1.10.1 Model Predictions ......................... 36<br />

1.10.2 Seizable Assets Calculation Details ............... 37<br />

1.10.3 Micro-Simulation Details ..................... 38<br />

2 Pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Welfare <strong>in</strong> Health Plan Choice 65<br />

2.1 Introduction ................................ 65<br />

2.2 Health Plan Pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Market Efficiency ............... 68<br />

2.3 Data <strong>and</strong> Environment .......................... 72<br />

2.3.1 Institutional Sett<strong>in</strong>g ....................... 72<br />

2.3.2 Data <strong>and</strong> Descriptive Statistics ................. 74<br />

2.4 Econometric Model ............................ 77<br />

2.4.1 Consumer Preferences, Plan Costs <strong>and</strong> Market Behavior ... 77<br />

2.4.2 Discussion of Model <strong>and</strong> Identification ............. 82<br />

2.4.3 Estimation Strategy ....................... 85<br />

2.4.4 Welfare Measurement ....................... 86<br />

2.5 Empirical Results ............................. 87<br />

2.5.1 Model Estimates ......................... 88<br />

2.5.2 Quantify<strong>in</strong>g Social Welfare Inefficiencies ............ 93<br />

x


2.5.3 The Value of Plan Choice .................... 96<br />

2.5.4 Discussion <strong>and</strong> Sensitivity Analysis ............... 97<br />

2.6 Conclusion ................................. 98<br />

2.7 Appendix to Chapter 2 .......................... 99<br />

2.7.1 Comparison to Dem<strong>and</strong> Estimates <strong>in</strong> Other Sett<strong>in</strong>gs ..... 99<br />

2.7.2 Alternative Specifications of the Dem<strong>and</strong> Model ........ 100<br />

3 Private Coverage <strong>and</strong> Public Costs: Identify<strong>in</strong>g the Effect of Private<br />

Supplemental Insurance on Medicare Spend<strong>in</strong>g 117<br />

3.1 Introduction ................................ 117<br />

3.2 Background ................................ 122<br />

3.3 Data .................................... 124<br />

3.4 Empirical Model ............................. 125<br />

3.4.1 Estimat<strong>in</strong>g equations ....................... 125<br />

3.4.2 Estimation approach ....................... 127<br />

3.5 Identify<strong>in</strong>g Variation ........................... 128<br />

3.5.1 The Instrument .......................... 128<br />

3.5.2 Potential Concerns ........................ 130<br />

3.6 Results <strong>and</strong> Discussion .......................... 132<br />

3.6.1 Premiums <strong>and</strong> Medigap Choice ................. 132<br />

3.6.2 Causal Impact on Costs ..................... 134<br />

3.6.3 Robustness <strong>and</strong> External Validity ................ 136<br />

3.7 Policy Counterfactuals .......................... 137<br />

3.8 Conclusion ................................. 139<br />

4 Do Expir<strong>in</strong>g Budgets Lead to Wasteful Year-End Spend<strong>in</strong>g? Evi-<br />

dence from Federal Procurement 153<br />

4.1 Introduction ................................ 153<br />

4.2 A Model of Wasteful Year-End Spend<strong>in</strong>g ................ 157<br />

4.2.1 The Basel<strong>in</strong>e Model ........................ 157<br />

4.2.2 Rollover Budget Authority .................... 159<br />

4.2.3 Extend<strong>in</strong>g the Model To Allow For Rollover .......... 160<br />

xi


4.3 Does Spend<strong>in</strong>g Spike at the End of the Year? ............. 161<br />

4.3.1 The Federal Procurement Data System ............. 163<br />

4.3.2 The With<strong>in</strong>-Year Pattern of Government Procurement Spend<strong>in</strong>g 164<br />

4.3.3 The Impact of Appropriations Tim<strong>in</strong>g on the With<strong>in</strong>-Year Pat-<br />

tern of Government Procurement Spend<strong>in</strong>g ........... 165<br />

4.4 Is End of Year Spend<strong>in</strong>g of Lower Quality? ............... 167<br />

4.4.1 I.T. Dashboard .......................... 168<br />

4.4.2 Data <strong>and</strong> Summary Statistics .................. 169<br />

4.4.3 The Relative Quality of Year-End I.T. Contracts ....... 172<br />

4.4.4 Sensitivity Analysis ........................ 174<br />

4.4.5 Why Are Year End Contracts of Lower Quality? ........ 176<br />

4.5 Do Rollover Provisions Raise Spend<strong>in</strong>g Quality? ............ 179<br />

4.5.1 The DOJ’s Rollover Authority .................. 179<br />

4.6 Conclusion ................................. 182<br />

xii


List of Tables<br />

1.1 Asset Exemption Laws by State ..................... 52<br />

1.2 Implied First Stage Estimates ...................... 53<br />

1.3 Basel<strong>in</strong>e Coverage Estimates ....................... 54<br />

1.4 Sensitivity Analysis of the Effect on Coverage ............. 55<br />

1.5 Heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> the Effect on Coverage ................. 56<br />

1.6 The Effect on Assets ........................... 57<br />

1.7 The Effect on Premiums ......................... 58<br />

1.8 Basel<strong>in</strong>e Costs Estimates ......................... 59<br />

1.9 Sensitivity Analysis of the Effect on Costs ............... 60<br />

1.10 Micro-Simulation Estimates of Percent Covered Without <strong>and</strong> With<br />

Bankruptcy Insurance by Insurance Status ............... 61<br />

1.11 Policy Counterfactuals .......................... 62<br />

1.12 Summary Statistics: Seizable Assets by Insurance Status ....... 63<br />

1.13 Summary Statistics: Medical Costs by Insurance Status ........ 63<br />

1.14 Summary Statistics: Premiums ..................... 64<br />

1.15 Costs <strong>and</strong> Premiums by Deductible Level ................ 64<br />

2.1 Risk <strong>and</strong> Demographics .......................... 102<br />

2.2 Plan Characteristics ........................... 103<br />

2.3 Risk <strong>and</strong> Demographics by Plan ..................... 104<br />

2.4 Dem<strong>and</strong> Model .............................. 105<br />

2.5 Costs <strong>and</strong> Bids .............................. 106<br />

2.6 Match<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Welfare under Alternative Contribution Policies .... 107<br />

2.7 Match<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Welfare by Risk Score Qu<strong>in</strong>tile ............. 108<br />

xiii


2.8 The Value of Plan Choice ........................ 109<br />

2.9 Alternative Dem<strong>and</strong> Model Specifications ................ 115<br />

3.1 Medicare Cost-Shar<strong>in</strong>g .......................... 141<br />

3.2 Summary Statistics by Supplemental Insurance Type ......... 142<br />

3.3 Medigap Enrollment <strong>and</strong> Plan Characteristics by Letter ........ 143<br />

3.4 HRR Level-Medicare Costs Tabulated By State ............ 144<br />

3.5 First Stage: OLS Estimates of Premiums on State <strong>and</strong> HRR Costs .. 145<br />

3.6 Second Stage: Marg<strong>in</strong>al Effects for Medigap Choice from Mult<strong>in</strong>omial<br />

Logit Model ................................ 146<br />

3.7 Third Stage: OLS <strong>and</strong> Full Model Estimates of Medical Costs on Medi-<br />

gap Indicator ............................... 147<br />

3.8 Robustness Checks: Key Parameter Estimates from Alternative Spec-<br />

ifications <strong>and</strong> Samples .......................... 148<br />

3.9 Policy Counterfactuals for Subsidies <strong>and</strong> Taxes of Medigap Premiums 149<br />

3.10 OLS Estimates of Premiums on HRR- <strong>and</strong> State-Level Medicare Costs 150<br />

3.11 Second Stage: 2SLS Estimates of Medigap Choice from L<strong>in</strong>ear Proba-<br />

bility Model ................................ 151<br />

3.12 Third Stage: 3SLS Estimates of Medical Costs on Medigap Indicator 152<br />

4.1 Summary Statistics: Federal Contract<strong>in</strong>g, Pooled 2004 to 2009 FPDS 187<br />

4.2 Year-End Contract Spend<strong>in</strong>g by Agency, Pooled 2004 to 2009 FPDS . 188<br />

4.3 Year-End Contract Spend<strong>in</strong>g By Selected Product or Service Code,<br />

Pooled 2004 to 2009 FPDS ........................ 189<br />

4.4 Summary Statistics: Major I.T. Projects as of March, 2010 ...... 190<br />

4.5 Summary Statistics: Quality Indexes <strong>and</strong> Project Characteristics for<br />

Major I.T. Projects ............................ 191<br />

4.6 Ordered Logit Regressions of Overall Rat<strong>in</strong>g on Last Week <strong>and</strong> Controls192<br />

4.7 Alternative Overall Rat<strong>in</strong>gs Specifications ............... 193<br />

4.8 Difference-<strong>in</strong>-Differences Estimates of Overall Rat<strong>in</strong>g on Justice <strong>and</strong><br />

Last Week ................................. 194<br />

xiv


4.9 First Week Contract Spend<strong>in</strong>g for Selected Product or Service Codes,<br />

Pooled 2004 to 2009 FPDS ........................ 195<br />

4.10 Ordered Logit Regressions of Sub<strong>in</strong>dexes on Last Week <strong>and</strong> Controls 196<br />

4.11 Year-End Contract Characteristics Regressions ............. 197<br />

4.12 Percent of Projects <strong>in</strong> I.T. Dashboard Data ............... 198<br />

xv


List of Figures<br />

1.1 Histogram of Seizable Assets by Insurance Status ........... 41<br />

1.2 Payments vs. Charges by Insurance Status ............... 42<br />

1.3 Provider Bill<strong>in</strong>g Decision: Submitted Bill vs. List Price of Medical Care 43<br />

1.4 Payments vs. Charges by Seizable Assets ................ 44<br />

1.5 Simulated Instrument by State ...................... 45<br />

1.6 Log Seizable Assets Percentiles by State for a Constant Sample of<br />

Households ................................ 46<br />

1.7 Seizable Homestead Equity <strong>in</strong> 2005 vs. 1920 for a Constant Sample of<br />

Households ................................ 47<br />

1.8 Insurance Coverage vs. Seizable Assets ................. 48<br />

1.9 Effect on Coverage on Samples Exclud<strong>in</strong>g Each State ......... 49<br />

1.10 Micro-Simulation Estimates of Percent Covered Without <strong>and</strong> With<br />

Bankruptcy Insurance by Deductible .................. 50<br />

1.11 The Insurance Generosity Gap ...................... 51<br />

2.3 Contributions <strong>and</strong> Bids Relative to Integrated HMO .......... 111<br />

2.4 Employer Contributions <strong>and</strong> Employee Characteristics ........ 112<br />

2.5 Costs by Risk Score ............................ 113<br />

2.6 Bids by Risk Score ............................ 114<br />

3.1 Example of Identify<strong>in</strong>g Variation .................... 140<br />

4.1 Federal Contract<strong>in</strong>g by Week, Pooled 2004 to 2009 FPDS ....... 183<br />

4.2 Year-End Spend<strong>in</strong>g by Appropriations Date .............. 184<br />

xvi


4.3 I.T. Contract<strong>in</strong>g by Week ........................ 185<br />

4.4 Year-End <strong>and</strong> Rest-of-Year Overall Rat<strong>in</strong>gs ............... 186<br />

xvii


Chapter 1<br />

Bankruptcy as Implicit Health<br />

Insurance<br />

1.1 Introduction<br />

There is a large literature <strong>in</strong> economics evaluat<strong>in</strong>g the effects of government policy<br />

on health <strong>in</strong>surance coverage <strong>in</strong> the United States. 1 The question of why households<br />

choose to be un<strong>in</strong>sured is less well understood. 2 To better underst<strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

coverage decision, this paper exam<strong>in</strong>es a mechanism that has received little attention:<br />

implicit <strong>in</strong>surance from the threat-po<strong>in</strong>t of personal bankruptcy.<br />

The implicit <strong>in</strong>surance from bankruptcy arises from the confluence of three factors.<br />

First, due to federal law, hospitals are required to provide emergency treatment on<br />

credit—<strong>and</strong> typically provide non-emergency care without any upfront payment as<br />

well. Second, under Chapter 7 of the U.S. bankruptcy code, households can discharge<br />

medical debt, giv<strong>in</strong>g up assets above asset exemption limits <strong>in</strong> return. 3 Third, because<br />

1 See ? for review of the take-up <strong>and</strong> crowd-out effects of <strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance expansions. See ? for<br />

a review of the impact of tax subsidies on the employer provision of <strong>in</strong>surance. See ? for a review<br />

of the effects of tax policy on <strong>in</strong>surance take-up <strong>in</strong> the non-group market.<br />

2 In a review of the literature ? concludes, “there are a variety of hypotheses for why so many<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals are un<strong>in</strong>sured, but no clear sense that this set of explanations can account for the 47<br />

million <strong>in</strong>dividuals.”<br />

3 The Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention <strong>and</strong> Consumer Protection Act (BAPCPA) of 2005 was implemented<br />

after the period I analyze. It prevents households with more than the state median <strong>in</strong>come<br />

1


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 2<br />

of the deadweight cost of the bankruptcy process, households <strong>and</strong> creditors have an<br />

<strong>in</strong>centive to negotiate payments without a formal bankruptcy fil<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Bankruptcy, as a result, provides households with a form of high-deductible health<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance. Households are exposed to the f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk from medical shocks up to<br />

the level of assets that can be seized <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>sured aga<strong>in</strong>st f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk<br />

above this level.<br />

Summary data on the un<strong>in</strong>sured suggest that this mechanism could be important.<br />

Figure 1.1 shows that un<strong>in</strong>sured households have vastly fewer seizable assets than<br />

households with private <strong>in</strong>surance. Sixty-three percent of the un<strong>in</strong>sured would give up<br />

less than $5,000 <strong>in</strong> a bankruptcy fil<strong>in</strong>g, compared to only 28 percent of the privately<br />

<strong>in</strong>sured. Figure 1.2 shows that payments by the un<strong>in</strong>sured are substantially lower<br />

when receiv<strong>in</strong>g a high volume of medical care. While payments by the privately<br />

<strong>in</strong>sured scale up proportionally with medical charges, payments by the un<strong>in</strong>sured are<br />

capped on average at just over $5,000.<br />

To more rigorously exam<strong>in</strong>e the mechanism, I construct a simple model of bankruptcy,<br />

medical bill<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance choice. The model predicts that, conditional on wealth,<br />

out-of-pocket medical payments should be decreas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the level of seizable assets for<br />

a given volume of medical care received. Hold<strong>in</strong>g wealth constant, households with<br />

fewer seizable assets should be less likely to purchase conventional coverage.<br />

I test these predictions us<strong>in</strong>g variation <strong>in</strong> the state-level asset exemption laws that<br />

specify the type <strong>and</strong> level of assets that can be seized <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy <strong>and</strong> detailed<br />

asset data from the restricted access Medical Expenditure Panel Survey (MEPS) <strong>and</strong><br />

the Panel Survey of Income Dynamics (PSID). The degree of cross-state variation<br />

<strong>in</strong> the asset exemption laws <strong>in</strong> substantial. Kansas, for example, allows households<br />

to exempt an unlimited amount of home equity <strong>and</strong> up to $40,000 <strong>in</strong> vehicle equity.<br />

Neighbor<strong>in</strong>g Nebraska allows households to keep no more than $12,500 <strong>in</strong> home equity<br />

or a $5,000 wildcard of any type of asset. Both states allow households to keep<br />

retirement assets. I construct a simulated <strong>in</strong>strument that isolates the variation <strong>in</strong><br />

seizable assets solely due to these laws, mechanically purg<strong>in</strong>g variation due to wealth<br />

from fil<strong>in</strong>g under Chapter 7 <strong>in</strong> most circumstances. The households most affected by the reform are<br />

unlikely to be marg<strong>in</strong>al to the mechanism I analyze.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 3<br />

<strong>and</strong> other household characteristics.<br />

Us<strong>in</strong>g this source of variation <strong>and</strong> cost data from the MEPS, I f<strong>in</strong>d that un<strong>in</strong>sured<br />

households with fewer seizable assets make lower out-of-pocket payments for a given<br />

level of medical care received. My preferred estimate <strong>in</strong>dicates that a log po<strong>in</strong>t drop<br />

<strong>in</strong> seizable assets reduces out-of-pocket payments by 37 percent. Consistent with the<br />

high-deductible nature of this <strong>in</strong>surance, the drop is larger for households that utilize<br />

more medical services as the “deductible” of this implicit <strong>in</strong>surance is more likely to<br />

b<strong>in</strong>d.<br />

Us<strong>in</strong>g the same source of variation <strong>and</strong> MEPS <strong>and</strong> PSID data, I f<strong>in</strong>d that house-<br />

holds with fewer seizable assets are less likely to have <strong>in</strong>surance. The estimates suggest<br />

that if the bankruptcy laws of the least debtor-friendly state of Delaware were applied<br />

nationally, 16.3 percent of the un<strong>in</strong>sured would buy health <strong>in</strong>surance. With a take-up<br />

semi-elasticity of -0.084 from the literature, achiev<strong>in</strong>g the same <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> take-up<br />

would require a premium subsidy of 44.0 percent. 4<br />

I use three strategies to address the concern that asset exemption laws may be<br />

correlated with unobserved state-level factors. The first strategy is to use variation<br />

due to 1920 homestead exemptions as an <strong>in</strong>strument. By us<strong>in</strong>g homestead exemptions<br />

from before the era of widespread health <strong>in</strong>surance, the <strong>in</strong>strument alleviates potential<br />

bias from factors that might have simultaneously caused changes <strong>in</strong> asset exemption<br />

law <strong>and</strong> the dependent variables over the course of the twentieth century. Moreover,<br />

historical evidence (e.g., ?) show<strong>in</strong>g that 1920 homestead exemption levels resulted<br />

from an idiosyncratic array of n<strong>in</strong>eteenth century historical circumstances dim<strong>in</strong>ishes<br />

the concern that this variable merely proxies for a persistent state characteristic (such<br />

as the strength of a pro-debtor political movement).<br />

The second strategy is to sequentially add fixed effects for Census Regions (e.g.,<br />

Northeast) <strong>and</strong> Census Divisions (e.g., New Engl<strong>and</strong>) to the ma<strong>in</strong> specification. If a<br />

spatially correlated unobserved factor is driv<strong>in</strong>g the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs, the results should change<br />

with the <strong>in</strong>clusion of these covariates. Stable estimates across these specifications<br />

mitigate this concern. The third strategy is to add controls for a rich set of potentially<br />

4 The -0.084 estimates is taken from ? <strong>and</strong> is based on premium variation due to state-level<br />

community rat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> premium compression regulations. As I discuss below, this estimate is <strong>in</strong> the<br />

center of the range <strong>in</strong> the literature.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 4<br />

relevant legislative factors. The fact that the estimates are uncharged by the <strong>in</strong>clusion<br />

of these covariates provides further support for the case that the identify<strong>in</strong>g variation<br />

is uncorrelated with unobserved state-level determ<strong>in</strong>ants of costs <strong>and</strong> coverage.<br />

I take the analysis a step further by calibrat<strong>in</strong>g a utility-based, micro-simulation<br />

model of <strong>in</strong>surance choice. The model is based on a nationally representative sample<br />

of households. Households face household-specific medical shock distributions that<br />

depend on the age <strong>and</strong> sex of each household member. To maximize their expected<br />

utility over wealth, households choose to either purchase conventional <strong>in</strong>surance at<br />

market premiums or rely on the high-deductible <strong>in</strong>surance from bankruptcy.<br />

I use this model to shed light on puzzles <strong>in</strong> the health policy literature. One of the<br />

puzzles I exam<strong>in</strong>e is the low take-up of high-deductible health plans (HDHP) by the<br />

un<strong>in</strong>sured (?). Proponents of these plans have argued that by offer<strong>in</strong>g lower premi-<br />

ums, HDHPs would exp<strong>and</strong> coverage among the un<strong>in</strong>sured. But because the implicit<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance from bankruptcy often resembles a high-deductible policy, HDHPs are rel-<br />

atively more likely to be crowded out by this mechanism. In the micro-simulation<br />

model, account<strong>in</strong>g for bankruptcy reduces the percentage of un<strong>in</strong>sured households<br />

projected to purchase a $1,000 deductible plan by 13 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts. For a $5,000<br />

deductible plan, bankruptcy reduces dem<strong>and</strong> by 37 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts, or from 43 to<br />

6percent.<br />

A second puzzle I exam<strong>in</strong>e is heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> the dem<strong>and</strong> for coverage. Without<br />

bankruptcy, households with <strong>and</strong> without <strong>in</strong>surance coverage are difficult to separate.<br />

Us<strong>in</strong>g variation <strong>in</strong> medical risk, tax exemptions, <strong>and</strong> adm<strong>in</strong>istrative costs, the model<br />

can separate the predicted coverage levels of un<strong>in</strong>sured <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>sured households by only<br />

14 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts. Because there are large differences <strong>in</strong> seizable assets across these<br />

groups, account<strong>in</strong>g for bankruptcy has a substantial <strong>in</strong>cremental effect, widen<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

gap <strong>in</strong> predicted coverage from 14 to 51 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts.<br />

The mechanism I study may be relevant to policy design. On the one h<strong>and</strong>, the<br />

implicit <strong>in</strong>surance from bankruptcy has obvious <strong>in</strong>efficiencies. Un<strong>in</strong>sured households<br />

receive a substantial amount of non-emergency medical care <strong>in</strong> emergency rooms,<br />

which are obviously not optimized for this purpose (?). At the same time, these<br />

households receive less preventative care than they would with conventional health


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 5<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance (?). There are deadweight costs to negotiation <strong>and</strong> collections under the<br />

threat-po<strong>in</strong>t of bankruptcy. And the fact that un<strong>in</strong>sured households are not exposed<br />

to the social cost of this implicit <strong>in</strong>surance means that too many households choose<br />

to be un<strong>in</strong>sured.<br />

Yet conventional health <strong>in</strong>surance has <strong>in</strong>efficiencies of its own. A particularly<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>efficiency relative to bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance is moral hazard. With con-<br />

ventional <strong>in</strong>surance, medical providers <strong>and</strong> patients often have <strong>in</strong>centives to supply<br />

<strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> excess medical care. Under the implicit <strong>in</strong>surance from bankruptcy,<br />

however, physicians are more likely to be exposed to the social cost of their deci-<br />

sions <strong>and</strong> patients have little leverage to dem<strong>and</strong> excess treatment. The result is that<br />

bankruptcy may be a lower moral hazard form of social <strong>in</strong>surance. 5<br />

While a comprehensive analysis of the costs <strong>and</strong> benefits of bankruptcy is overly<br />

ambitious, I can exam<strong>in</strong>e one key tension between these forms of <strong>in</strong>surance with the<br />

micro-simulation model. In particular, the model allows me to trade off the benefit of<br />

bankruptcy as a lower moral hazard form of <strong>in</strong>surance aga<strong>in</strong>st the <strong>in</strong>efficiency due to<br />

households not fac<strong>in</strong>g the full social cost from be<strong>in</strong>g un<strong>in</strong>sured. This tradeoff suggests<br />

a corrective system of “Pigovian penalties” that expose households to the full social<br />

cost of the implicit <strong>in</strong>surance they receive. 6<br />

With the optimal penalty of $218 per person on average, about 7 percent of<br />

the un<strong>in</strong>sured take up coverage <strong>and</strong> aggregate surplus <strong>in</strong>creases by a small $4 to $5<br />

per person. Analyzed <strong>in</strong> this framework, the penalties under the Patient Projection<br />

<strong>and</strong> Affordable Care Act (PPACA), which average $418 per person, are too large,<br />

decreas<strong>in</strong>g aggregate surplus by $9 to $13 per person on average. By effectively<br />

elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g the low moral hazard option, the counterfactual of mak<strong>in</strong>g medical debt<br />

non-dischargeable <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy reduces surplus by an average of $36 to $43 per<br />

person. While the exact welfare numbers should be viewed with some caution, the<br />

exercise suggests that dramatically reduc<strong>in</strong>g bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance—while hav<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

5 Estimates of the moral hazard effects from conventional health <strong>in</strong>surance, when identified off<br />

large medical costs, are <strong>in</strong>cremental to any moral hazard effects from the implicit <strong>in</strong>surance from<br />

bankruptcy.<br />

6 For this exercise, I assume that un<strong>in</strong>sured households are not already subsidized through the<br />

tax code or some other channel.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 6<br />

superficial benefit of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g conventional coverage—may not be socially desirable.<br />

By study<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>teraction between implicit <strong>and</strong> conventional <strong>in</strong>surance, this pa-<br />

per is closely related to the literature on long-term care <strong>in</strong>surance <strong>and</strong> the implicit<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance from spend<strong>in</strong>g down assets <strong>and</strong> qualify<strong>in</strong>g for Medicare, such as ?. Like<br />

them, I f<strong>in</strong>d that implicit <strong>in</strong>surance can cause substantial crowd-out. It is more gen-<br />

erally related to a literature <strong>in</strong> macroeconomics that assesses the equilibrium effects<br />

of bankruptcy as a form of consumption <strong>in</strong>surance aga<strong>in</strong>st a range of different shocks,<br />

<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g those related to earn<strong>in</strong>gs, divorce, childbear<strong>in</strong>g, lawsuits, <strong>and</strong> medical bills<br />

(??). By exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g unpaid care, this paper is also related to ? <strong>and</strong> ?, who f<strong>in</strong>d a<br />

negative association between measures of charity care <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance coverage. And<br />

this paper shares similarities with a literature that exam<strong>in</strong>es the effect of medical debt<br />

on bankruptcy fil<strong>in</strong>gs (e.g., ???), although unlike these papers, I treat bankruptcy as<br />

threat-po<strong>in</strong>t, not a dependent variable to be expla<strong>in</strong>ed. In this, my approach more<br />

closely resembles the “<strong>in</strong>formal bankruptcy” viewpo<strong>in</strong>t advanced by ?, who show that<br />

credit card debt is charged off without a bankruptcy fil<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the majority of cases.<br />

The rest of the paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 presents the <strong>in</strong>stitutional<br />

background <strong>and</strong> a simple model. Section 3 provides an overview of the data. Sections<br />

4 discusses the identification strategy. The ma<strong>in</strong> empirical results are presented <strong>in</strong><br />

Sections 5 <strong>and</strong> 6. The micro-simulation model is presented <strong>in</strong> Section 7. Section 8<br />

discusses puzzles <strong>in</strong> the literature <strong>and</strong> policy implications. Section 9 concludes.<br />

1.2 Bankruptcy as a Form of High-Deductible Health<br />

Insurance<br />

1.2.1 Institutional Background<br />

The implicit <strong>in</strong>surance from bankruptcy arises from the comb<strong>in</strong>ation of three <strong>in</strong>sti-<br />

tutional features: the fact that most medical care is provided on credit even when<br />

repayment is unlikely, the ability of households to discharge this debt <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>centive for households <strong>and</strong> creditors to come to a negotiated solution to<br />

avoid the deadweight loss from a formal bankruptcy fil<strong>in</strong>g.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 7<br />

The Emergency Medical Treatment <strong>and</strong> Active Labor Act (EMTALA) requires<br />

that hospitals treat patients with emergency medical conditions, <strong>and</strong> prohibits them<br />

from delay<strong>in</strong>g treatment to <strong>in</strong>quire about <strong>in</strong>surance status or means of payment. 7 As<br />

a matter of practice, most hospitals provide non-emergency medical care on credit as<br />

well. Hospitals generally lack the <strong>in</strong>frastructure to bill patients at the po<strong>in</strong>t of service<br />

(?) <strong>and</strong> rarely deny service when repayment is unlikely. 8<br />

Hav<strong>in</strong>g received medical care on credit, bankruptcy law allows households to write<br />

off this debt <strong>in</strong> exchange for assets or future earn<strong>in</strong>gs. Chapter 7 is the most pop-<br />

ular form of personal bankruptcy, account<strong>in</strong>g for about 70 percent of all fil<strong>in</strong>gs (?).<br />

Under Chapter 7, households can discharge most unsecured debt such as credit card<br />

debt, <strong>in</strong>stallment loans, <strong>and</strong> medical bills. In return, creditors can seize assets above<br />

exemption levels that vary by asset type <strong>and</strong> state of residence.<br />

Chapter 13 is the other bankruptcy option. Under Chapter 13, households dis-<br />

charge most unsecured debt <strong>in</strong> exchange for payments out of disposable <strong>in</strong>come over<br />

the follow<strong>in</strong>g 3 to 5 years. By statute, these payments must be of at least the value<br />

that creditors would receive <strong>in</strong> Chapter 7. They are rarely larger because, <strong>in</strong> the<br />

period I study, all households have the option to file for Chapter 7. 9 Follow<strong>in</strong>g ?, I<br />

use seizable assets under Chapter 7 to characterize payments under both chapters of<br />

the bankruptcy code.<br />

Households, however, do not have to formally declare bankruptcy to receive the<br />

implicit <strong>in</strong>surance it provides. Under the threat-po<strong>in</strong>t of bankruptcy, households <strong>and</strong><br />

medical providers often resolve payments without an actual bankruptcy fil<strong>in</strong>g. There<br />

are multiple junctures where this occurs. Discounts on the list price of treatment—<br />

known as charity care—are offered at the po<strong>in</strong>t of service to the obviously <strong>in</strong>digent. 10<br />

7 U.S.C. 42 §1395dd.<br />

8 In a survey of nonprofit hospitals, 90 percent reported never deny<strong>in</strong>g any medical services to<br />

patients with no <strong>in</strong>surance (?). For-profit hospitals seem to operate similarly. For example, ?<br />

rejects the hypothesis that for-profit hospitals have a lower preference for charity care. ? f<strong>in</strong>d that<br />

the majority of emergency departments offer preventative care to un<strong>in</strong>sured patients.<br />

9 The Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention <strong>and</strong> Consumer Protection Act (BAPCPA), effective <strong>in</strong> October<br />

2005, established a “means test” for Chapter 7. It restricted households earn<strong>in</strong>g more than<br />

the state median <strong>in</strong>come from fil<strong>in</strong>g under Chapter 7 <strong>in</strong> most circumstances. The households most<br />

effected by the reform are unlikely to be marg<strong>in</strong>al to the mechanism I analyze.<br />

10 Federal <strong>and</strong> state laws also <strong>in</strong>fluence charity care provision. Nonprofits use charity care to meet


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 8<br />

After treatment, many hospitals encourage f<strong>in</strong>ancially strapped households to nego-<br />

tiate discounts, requir<strong>in</strong>g the submission of <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> assets (e.g.,<br />

W-2s <strong>and</strong> mortgage payments) as part of their charity care applications. 11 Even when<br />

charity care is not provided, the lion’s share of medical debt is charged off <strong>in</strong> the col-<br />

lection process. Despite contract<strong>in</strong>g with debt collection agencies, providers recover<br />

only about 10 to 20 percent of bills submitted to the un<strong>in</strong>sured (?).<br />

Overall, bad debt from the un<strong>in</strong>sured was estimated at about $16 to $18 billion<br />

<strong>in</strong> 2004 (LeCuyer <strong>and</strong> S<strong>in</strong>ghal, 2007). While the exact proportion of debt discharged<br />

without a bankruptcy fil<strong>in</strong>g is unknown, ? f<strong>in</strong>d that the ratio of “medical” to “non-<br />

medical” bankruptcies, accord<strong>in</strong>g to their def<strong>in</strong>ition, is the same for households with<br />

<strong>and</strong> without <strong>in</strong>surance coverage, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that a large portion of the un<strong>in</strong>sured’s<br />

medical debt is charged off outside of formal bankruptcy. This is not unique to<br />

medical debt. ? report that the majority of credit card debt is charged off <strong>in</strong> what<br />

they call “<strong>in</strong>formal bankruptcy.”<br />

1.2.2 A Model of Bankruptcy as High-Deductible Health In-<br />

surance<br />

To br<strong>in</strong>g together these <strong>in</strong>stitutional features, I build a stylized model of households,<br />

medical providers, <strong>and</strong> bankruptcy. Households have a representative agent with<br />

expected utility preferences over wealth w = w E +w S , composed of exempt assets w E<br />

(net wealth that cannot be seized <strong>in</strong> a bankruptcy fill<strong>in</strong>g) <strong>and</strong> seizable assets w S (net<br />

wealth that can be seized by creditors). 12 They face medical shocks with list price<br />

m drawn from distribution M <strong>and</strong> choose whether to purchase health <strong>in</strong>surance to<br />

protect aga<strong>in</strong>st this f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk.<br />

Medical providers are obligated to provide medical services m <strong>and</strong> then attempt<br />

their Community Benefit requirement. Some states subsidize care to the <strong>in</strong>digent through unpaid<br />

care pools. I account for these factors <strong>in</strong> the empirical analysis.<br />

11 When this <strong>in</strong>formation is not provided, hospitals run credit checks on <strong>in</strong>debted patients, fil<strong>in</strong>g<br />

suit if they f<strong>in</strong>d evidence of a mortgage or sav<strong>in</strong>gs that could be claimed (“In Their Debt,” Baltimore<br />

Sun, December 12, 2008 to December 24th, 2008).<br />

12 I discuss endogeniz<strong>in</strong>g wealth at the end of this section.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 11<br />

Prediction 2. Hold<strong>in</strong>g overall wealth constant, the will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay for <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

v—<strong>and</strong> therefore <strong>in</strong>surance coverage—is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the level of seizable assets w S .<br />

Because the implicit <strong>in</strong>surance from bankruptcy is a substitute for conventional health<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance, households with more seizable assets have a higher will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay for<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance <strong>and</strong> are ceteris paribus more likely to be <strong>in</strong>sured. I derive the prediction <strong>in</strong><br />

Appendix Section 1.10.1.<br />

The prediction is robust to natural extensions of the model. For example, allow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>sured households to receive more or better medical treatment (?) <strong>in</strong>creases the<br />

<strong>in</strong>centive to purchase coverage, but households with fewer seizable assets are still<br />

relatively less likely to <strong>in</strong>sure. Similarly, <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the cost of bankruptcy to account<br />

for factors such as stigma (?) or reduced future access to credit (?) does not affect the<br />

basic prediction. And endogeniz<strong>in</strong>g the level of seizable <strong>and</strong> exempt assets actually<br />

strengthens the relationship between <strong>in</strong>surance coverage <strong>and</strong> seizable assets because<br />

households that choose to forgo coverage have an additional <strong>in</strong>centive to reduce their<br />

seizable asset hold<strong>in</strong>gs.<br />

A more subtle po<strong>in</strong>t relates to the <strong>in</strong>formation available to households. The model<br />

assumes that households know their level of seizable assets w S <strong>and</strong> their health risk.<br />

Obviously this is an exaggeration. What matters is that households have some knowl-<br />

edge of the f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk from forgo<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>surance. For example, if households learn<br />

from the news-media or peers that medical providers <strong>in</strong> their community frequently<br />

seize home equity, then homeowners may be more likely to purchase coverage—even<br />

if they know noth<strong>in</strong>g about the mechanism.<br />

1.3 Data Overview<br />

I use two ma<strong>in</strong> data sources to test the predictions of the model. I exam<strong>in</strong>e the effect<br />

of bankruptcy on medical costs us<strong>in</strong>g data from the 2000 to 2005 waves of the Medical<br />

Expenditure Panel Survey (MEPS). The survey has detailed <strong>in</strong>formation on medical<br />

costs <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance coverage. At the Data Center, encrypted state identifiers <strong>and</strong>


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 12<br />

newly edited asset <strong>and</strong> debt variables are also available. 17<br />

I exam<strong>in</strong>e the effects on coverage us<strong>in</strong>g the MEPS data <strong>and</strong> the 1999 to 2005 waves<br />

of the biennial Panel Survey of Income Dynamics (PSID). The survey has <strong>public</strong> use<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>in</strong>surance coverage, assets <strong>and</strong> debts variables, <strong>and</strong> state identifiers.<br />

Because the state of residence is non-encrypted <strong>in</strong> the PSID, I use this dataset for<br />

the primary <strong>in</strong>surance coverage analysis <strong>and</strong> replicate the results <strong>in</strong> the MEPS.<br />

In both data sets, I aggregate the <strong>in</strong>dividual-level data to the household level <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>flation-adjust monetary variables to 2005 dollars us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U. I also exclude<br />

households with one or more members enrolled <strong>in</strong> <strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance or a head age 65<br />

or older due to their eligibility for <strong>public</strong> Medicare <strong>in</strong>surance. 18 This leaves me with<br />

34,841 observations <strong>in</strong> the MEPS <strong>and</strong> 22,844 observations <strong>in</strong> the PSID.<br />

1.3.1 Asset Exemptions<br />

I codify assets exemptions us<strong>in</strong>g ?, a do-it-yourself guide to personal bankruptcy.<br />

Table 1.1 shows these exemptions. Contemporaneous homestead exemptions exhibit<br />

substantial variation, rang<strong>in</strong>g from zero <strong>in</strong> seven states to unlimited <strong>in</strong> eight others;<br />

vehicle exemptions range from zero <strong>in</strong> 15 states to at least $10,000 <strong>in</strong> five others;<br />

<strong>and</strong> wildcard exemptions, which can be applied to any asset, show a similar degree<br />

of variation. California residents can file under two different exemption systems, <strong>and</strong><br />

residents of 14 states can file under the federal exemption system if they choose. The<br />

last column shows homestead exemptions <strong>in</strong> the year of 1920 from ?. 19<br />

1.3.2 Seizable Assets<br />

Let i denote households <strong>and</strong> j denoted states. Seizable assets are a function of house-<br />

hold assets <strong>and</strong> debts <strong>and</strong> exemptions laws, denoted by vectors wi <strong>and</strong> ej. Follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the general structure of ?, seizable asset can be decomposed <strong>in</strong>to assets that can be<br />

17 ? f<strong>in</strong>d that the estimates of net worth <strong>in</strong> the MEPS are comparable to those <strong>in</strong> the Survey of<br />

Income <strong>and</strong> Program Participation (SIPP). My analysis does not go back before 2000 because when<br />

I started the project only asset <strong>and</strong> debt data from the 2000 to 2005 period had been edited.<br />

18 In the MEPS, I also drop the 3.6 percent of households with miss<strong>in</strong>g wealth variables.<br />

19 States that did not exist <strong>and</strong> states that had only acre-based exemptions are denoted as miss<strong>in</strong>g.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 14<br />

Appendix Section 1.10.2.<br />

1.3.3 Medical Costs<br />

Medical costs variables are shown <strong>in</strong> Appendix Table 1.13. Annual medical charges,<br />

def<strong>in</strong>ed as the list price of medical services used that year, average $6,647 per house-<br />

hold. Total payments, def<strong>in</strong>ed as the sum of payments received, are less than charges<br />

due to both discounts negotiated by <strong>in</strong>surance providers <strong>and</strong> medical care provided<br />

as charity care or bad debt. For privately <strong>in</strong>sured households, total payments average<br />

$4,480 per household. N<strong>in</strong>ety-four percent of these payments are either out-of-pocket<br />

payments or payments made by private <strong>in</strong>surance providers. For the un<strong>in</strong>sured, to-<br />

tal payments average $1,267 per household. Fifty-two percent of these payments are<br />

out-of-pocket. Miscellaneous payments, such as payments from charity care pools,<br />

worker’s compensation, or automobile <strong>in</strong>surance, account for most of the rest.<br />

In the empirical analysis, I use the out-of-pocket payments variable to measure<br />

the f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk faced by the un<strong>in</strong>sured. While this variable will accurately capture<br />

f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk <strong>in</strong> most circumstances, it may <strong>in</strong>accurately measure f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk for<br />

two reasons. First, out-of-pocket payments overstate f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk when these pay-<br />

ments are put on a credit card that is ultimately discharged <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy. Because<br />

households with fewer seizable assets are more likely to discharge credit card debt,<br />

out-of-pocket payments may overestimate f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk for some low seizable assets<br />

households.<br />

Second, out-of-pocket payments may understate f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk when medical providers<br />

break up large bills <strong>in</strong>to <strong>in</strong>stallments s<strong>in</strong>ce households are not prompted to report pay-<br />

ments that extend beyond the survey period. Because households with more seizable<br />

assets are more likely to make these large, multi-<strong>in</strong>stallment payments, out-of-pocket<br />

payments may understate f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk for high seizable assets households. Both<br />

overstated f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk for low seizable assets households <strong>and</strong> understated f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

risk for households with high seizable assets may lead to attenuated estimates of the<br />

relationship between seizable assets <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk as measured by out-of-pocket<br />

payments, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that the empirical estimates should be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as a lower


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 15<br />

bound of the effect of bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance on household f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk.<br />

I use Relative Risk Scores to control for medical utilization. As I discuss <strong>in</strong> Section<br />

1.4, controll<strong>in</strong>g for utilization is important because the direction of the unconditional<br />

relationship between out-of-pocket payments <strong>and</strong> seizable assets <strong>in</strong> theoretically am-<br />

biguous. To control for utilization, I use the Relative Risk Score variable constructed<br />

us<strong>in</strong>g the RiskSmart Version 2.2 software created by DxCG Inc. 23 This software uses<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation on age, sex, <strong>and</strong> medical diagnoses to project expected medical utiliza-<br />

tion based on regression models developed by the company. Because the software<br />

does not use geographical <strong>in</strong>formation to project utilization, the Relative Risk Score<br />

is orthogonal to asset exemption laws <strong>and</strong> other state-level factors.<br />

1.3.4 Insurance Premiums<br />

I conduct additional analysis us<strong>in</strong>g data on health <strong>in</strong>surance premiums <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>di-<br />

vidual market. In particular, I use data on premium quotes <strong>in</strong> each state that are<br />

listed on eHealthInsurance, a website that aggregates premium quotes from most of<br />

the major <strong>in</strong>surance providers. The data I use were collected <strong>in</strong> November, 2010.<br />

I collect premiums <strong>in</strong> each state for a 30-year-old non-smok<strong>in</strong>g male. Because pre-<br />

miums quotes are zip code specific, the data are collected for a zip code r<strong>and</strong>omly<br />

selected from the 10 most populous zip codes <strong>in</strong> the state. Along with premiums,<br />

I collect data on the <strong>in</strong>surance provider, plan br<strong>and</strong> name, deductible, co<strong>in</strong>surance<br />

rate, <strong>and</strong> co-payment for a office visit. I def<strong>in</strong>e an <strong>in</strong>surance plan as all observations<br />

with the same <strong>in</strong>surer, br<strong>and</strong> name, deductible, co<strong>in</strong>surance <strong>and</strong> co-payment. Table<br />

1.14 shows basic summary statistics for the data. The data set covers 41 states <strong>and</strong><br />

1,891 plans. The mean premium is $103 per month, the mean deductible is $3,351,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the mean co<strong>in</strong>surance rate is 15 percent.<br />

23 See form HC-092 on the MEPS website for a full description of the construction of this variable.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 17<br />

levels of seizable assets. For small charges the three groups make similar out-of-pocket<br />

payments, consistent with most households be<strong>in</strong>g below the cap. For large charges,<br />

out-of-pocket payments sharply diverge. While households with less than $10,000 <strong>in</strong><br />

seizable assets have their out-of-pocket payments capped, households with more than<br />

$50,000 <strong>in</strong> seizable assets see their out-of-pocket payments cont<strong>in</strong>ue to scale up with<br />

charges, consistent with a cap that is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> seizable assets.<br />

To test the capp<strong>in</strong>g-of-cost prediction more rigorously, I estimate regression mod-<br />

els of out-of-pocket payments on seizable assets, condition<strong>in</strong>g on the level of medical<br />

care received. Controll<strong>in</strong>g for medical utilization is important because the sign of<br />

the unconditional effect of seizable assets on out-of-pocket payments is theoretically<br />

ambiguous. To see this, consider the effect of reduc<strong>in</strong>g a household’s level of seiz-<br />

able assets. Due to the mechanical effect of the implicit <strong>in</strong>surance from bankruptcy,<br />

out-of-pocket payments should decrease. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, due to moral hazard,<br />

households may <strong>in</strong>crease their medical utilization, rais<strong>in</strong>g out-of-pocket costs <strong>and</strong><br />

potentially offsett<strong>in</strong>g the mechanical effect <strong>in</strong> the opposite direction.<br />

For the analysis, I restrict the sample to un<strong>in</strong>sured households with positive med-<br />

ical utilization. Lett<strong>in</strong>g i denote households <strong>and</strong> j denote states, the second stage<br />

cost equation takes the form<br />

ln(OOPij +1)=βwln(w S ij)+f(RRSi; βRRS)+XijβX + νij, (1.4)<br />

where the dependent variable is log out-of-pocket payments, w S ij is seizable assets,<br />

f(RRSi; β k m) is a fourth-order polynomial <strong>in</strong> the Relative Risk Score, Xij is a vector<br />

of household <strong>and</strong> state characteristics, <strong>and</strong> νij is the error term. 26 The capp<strong>in</strong>g of<br />

cost prediction is supported by a positive coefficient on seizable assets (βw > 0).<br />

1.4.3 Cross-State Variation<br />

Consistently estimat<strong>in</strong>g the parameters of <strong>in</strong>terest poses four dist<strong>in</strong>ct identification<br />

problems. The first issue is omitted variables: that coverage or costs <strong>and</strong> seizable<br />

26 The depend variable is rarely zero. In the sample analyzed, less than 4 percent of households<br />

make zero out-of-pocket payments.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 20<br />

or coverage over the course of the twentieth century. Moreover, historical evidence<br />

shows that 1920 homestead exemption levels resulted from an idiosyncratic array<br />

of n<strong>in</strong>eteenth century historical circumstances. Describ<strong>in</strong>g the key factors driv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the establishment of homestead exemptions <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eteenth century, ? cites no<br />

less diverse a list than “Texas colonizers <strong>and</strong> western developers, labor <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong><br />

reformers, antimonopoly Jacksonian egalitarians, defenders of family security <strong>and</strong><br />

women’s property rights, southern planters <strong>and</strong> yeomen devastated by the Civil War.”<br />

These heterogenous causes reduce the concern that historical homestead exemptions<br />

merely proxy for a persistent state-level characteristic such as the strength of the<br />

pro-debtor political movement.<br />

Importantly, historical homestead exemptions are also a good predictor of con-<br />

temporaneous exemptions values. 27 Figure 1.7 shows this graphically, plott<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

average level of seizable home equity for a constant, nationally representative sample<br />

of households under 2005 homestead exemptions (y-axis) <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted 1920<br />

homestead exemptions (x-axis) <strong>in</strong> each state. The plot also shows the fitted l<strong>in</strong>e from<br />

a bivariate regression. As the slope coefficient <strong>in</strong>dicates, homestead exemptions have<br />

become less generous over time, with seizable assets <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g on average by 90 per-<br />

cent. The R-squared value is 0.43, with the New Engl<strong>and</strong> states <strong>in</strong> the lower right<br />

corner be<strong>in</strong>g the most prom<strong>in</strong>ent outliers. 28<br />

I take two further approaches to reduce the concern that unobservable factors<br />

are driv<strong>in</strong>g the effect. The first is to sequentially add controls for Census Regions<br />

(e.g., Northeast) <strong>and</strong> Census Divisions (e.g., New Engl<strong>and</strong>) to the ma<strong>in</strong> specification.<br />

Stable results across these specifications should address the concern that the effects<br />

are be<strong>in</strong>g driven by a spatially-correlated, unobserved factor.<br />

The second is to control for a rich set of state-level legislative covariates. In<br />

the coverage equations, I control for <strong>in</strong>surance market regulations (e.g., community<br />

rat<strong>in</strong>g requirements, coverage m<strong>and</strong>ates) that may affect premiums. 29 While the<br />

27Many of the changes s<strong>in</strong>ce 1920 have simply been <strong>in</strong>flation updates passed by <strong>in</strong>dividual state<br />

legislatures (?).<br />

28A keyword search of newspaper articles <strong>in</strong> a six-month w<strong>in</strong>dow around major changes <strong>in</strong> Massachusetts<br />

<strong>and</strong> Connecticut assets exemptions failed to reveal any <strong>in</strong>formation on the reasons for<br />

these <strong>in</strong>creases.<br />

29The data on these regulations was taken from a Blue Cross Blue Shield (2002) compilation


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 21<br />

<strong>public</strong>ly <strong>in</strong>sured are excluded from the basel<strong>in</strong>e sample, correlation between asset<br />

exemption laws <strong>and</strong> eligibility thresholds for <strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance programs might bias the<br />

estimates though sample selection. To assuage this concern, I estimate the regression<br />

models on samples exclud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>public</strong>ly <strong>in</strong>sured. I also control for<br />

the presence <strong>and</strong> generosity of Medicaid Medically Needy programs that provide an<br />

alternative form of safety net coverage. 30 In the cost equations, I control for hospital<br />

characteristics <strong>and</strong> other state-level factors (e.g., share of private hospitals) that may<br />

affect out-of-pocket payments. 31<br />

1.5 The Effect on Insurance Coverage<br />

1.5.1 First Stage Estimates<br />

Table 1.2 shows implied first stage regressions of log seizable assets on different <strong>in</strong>stru-<br />

mental variables. Column 1 shows estimates with the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument. Columns<br />

2 <strong>and</strong> 3 show estimates with <strong>in</strong>struments that isolate the variation due to seizable<br />

homestead equity <strong>and</strong> seizable non-homestead assets. These <strong>in</strong>struments are calcu-<br />

lated by tak<strong>in</strong>g a constant, nationally representative of households <strong>and</strong> calculat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

their level of seizable homestead <strong>and</strong> non-homestead equity as though they lived <strong>in</strong><br />

each state. Column 4 shows estimates us<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>strument that isolates variation<br />

due to 1920 homestead exemptions. All the specifications <strong>in</strong>clude demographic con-<br />

trols (age group, family structure, race, education, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>come), state controls (mean<br />

<strong>in</strong>come, percent unemployed, percent covered by Medicaid), <strong>and</strong> year fixed effects.<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>in</strong> all specifications here <strong>and</strong> throughout the paper are clustered at<br />

the state level. The <strong>in</strong>struments have substantial power. The basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument<br />

has an F-statistic of nearly 500 (column 1) <strong>and</strong> even the <strong>in</strong>strument based on 1920<br />

gracious shared by Am<strong>and</strong>a Kowalski.<br />

30I thank Jay Bhattacharya for alternat<strong>in</strong>g me to the presence of these programs. I use 2003 data<br />

on these programs taken from ?.<br />

31In particular, I control for the share of private <strong>and</strong> nonprofit hospitals, taken from the Hospital<br />

Statistics 2005 published by the American Hospital Association. I control for Disproportionate Share<br />

Hospital payments per 1,000 residents taken from the Kaiser Family Foundation. I control for the<br />

number of Federally Qualified Health Centers per 100,000 residents.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 22<br />

homestead exemptions has an F-statistic over 20 (column 4).<br />

1.5.2 Basel<strong>in</strong>e Coverage Estimates<br />

Before turn<strong>in</strong>g to the regression estimates, Figure 1.8 presents visual evidence on the<br />

crowd-out prediction. Plots on the same row show the exact same data. Datapo<strong>in</strong>ts<br />

are <strong>in</strong>dicated with state abbreviations <strong>in</strong> the plots <strong>in</strong> the left column <strong>and</strong> with circles<br />

proportional to the number of observations <strong>in</strong> the plots <strong>in</strong> the right column. Panels<br />

A <strong>and</strong> B plot <strong>in</strong>surance coverage aga<strong>in</strong>st seizable assets averaged by state. In the raw<br />

data, there is a strong upward-slopp<strong>in</strong>g relationship. The relationship is consistent<br />

across most states, with the outliers ma<strong>in</strong>ly states with very few observations. Panels<br />

C <strong>and</strong> D plot <strong>in</strong>surance coverage aga<strong>in</strong>st the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument averaged by state—<br />

the graphical analogue to a bivariate reduced form regressions. The upward-slop<strong>in</strong>g<br />

relationship is similar although the figures are more noisy. (I discuss Panels E <strong>and</strong> F<br />

below.)<br />

Table 1.3 presents the basel<strong>in</strong>e regression specifications. The first four columns<br />

show OLS estimates. Column 1 only has controls for year fixed effects. Column 2 adds<br />

the demographic <strong>and</strong> state controls. Columns 3 <strong>and</strong> 4 add controls for wealth <strong>and</strong><br />

premiums. 32 S<strong>in</strong>ce wealth <strong>and</strong> premiums may be directly affected by asset exemption<br />

laws, the parameter estimates with these controls are <strong>in</strong>appropriate for counterfac-<br />

tuals <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g changes <strong>in</strong> these exemptions. The coefficient on log seizable assets is<br />

6.13 <strong>in</strong> column 1 <strong>and</strong> about 2.5 across the other specifications. The similar estimates<br />

with the wealth <strong>and</strong> premium controls suggest that the effect is not mediated through<br />

these channels. 33<br />

Columns 5 to 8 show the 2SLS estimates with the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument (column 1<br />

of Table 1.2), add<strong>in</strong>g controls <strong>in</strong> the same manner as columns 1 through 4. The co-<br />

efficient on log seizable assets is 5.43 <strong>in</strong> the preferred specification with demographic<br />

32The premium <strong>in</strong>dex is state fixed effects from a regression of log premiums on plan <strong>and</strong> state<br />

fixed effects.<br />

33The slight <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> columns 4 <strong>and</strong> 8 is due to the fact that premium data is only available<br />

for a subset of states. When compared to a specification without this control estimated on the same<br />

sample, controll<strong>in</strong>g for premiums very slightly reduces the coefficient on log seizable assets. This is<br />

consistent with a negative correlation between asset exemption levels <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance premiums.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 23<br />

<strong>and</strong> state controls (column 6) <strong>and</strong> significantly positive at more than the 0.1 percent<br />

level. Like the OLS specifications, add<strong>in</strong>g controls for wealth (column 7) <strong>and</strong> pre-<br />

miums (column 8) has little effect. The larger 2SLS estimates are consistent with<br />

measurement error attenuat<strong>in</strong>g the coefficient of <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> the OLS specifications.<br />

The reduced form panels of Figure 1.8, discussed above, suggested that Texas<br />

might be important to the 2SLS results. Figure 1.9 exam<strong>in</strong>es the robustness of the<br />

estimates to this type of concern by show<strong>in</strong>g the coefficient on log seizable assets<br />

from 51 separate regressions of the preferred specification (column 6 of Table 1.3)<br />

that sequentially drop households from the <strong>in</strong>dicated state. The figure shows that<br />

neither Texas—nor any other state for that matter—is driv<strong>in</strong>g the results. Dropp<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Texas does slightly reduce the coefficient on log seizable assets. However, the estimate<br />

without Texas is significantly greater than zero <strong>and</strong> slightly larger than the estimate<br />

that excludes the state of Arizona.<br />

1.5.3 Sensitivity Analysis<br />

As discussed above, I address the potential bias from endogenous asset exemption laws<br />

with three strategies. I <strong>in</strong>clude controls for state legislative factors. I add controls<br />

for Census Regions (e.g., Northeast) <strong>and</strong> Census Divisions (e.g,. New Engl<strong>and</strong>). And<br />

I show specifications that use variation due to 1920 homestead exemptions as an<br />

<strong>in</strong>strument.<br />

Column 1 of Table 1.4 presents estimates of the preferred specification on a sam-<br />

ple that <strong>in</strong>cludes households with <strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance <strong>and</strong> column 2 adds controls for<br />

state <strong>in</strong>surance regulations <strong>and</strong> Medicaid Medically Needy programs to the preferred<br />

specification. Columns 3 <strong>and</strong> 4 sequentially add fixed effects for Census Regions <strong>and</strong><br />

Census Divisions. The coefficient on log seizable assets is stable across these speci-<br />

fications, reduc<strong>in</strong>g concerns that the estimates are driven by unobserved state level<br />

factors.<br />

Column 5 applies a variant of the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument that is calculated by averag-<br />

<strong>in</strong>g log seizable assets for the constant, nationally representative sample of households<br />

by age-by-educations groups rather than at the population level. The coefficient on


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 24<br />

log seizable assets is very similar with this <strong>in</strong>strument. Columns 6 <strong>and</strong> 7 apply <strong>in</strong>-<br />

struments that isolate the variation due to seizable homestead equity <strong>and</strong> seizable<br />

non-homestead assets respectively. The coefficient is a smaller 4.53 (p-value ¡ 0.05)<br />

when estimated us<strong>in</strong>g variation <strong>in</strong> homestead exemptions <strong>and</strong> a larger 6.16 (p-value<br />

¡0.01) when estimated us<strong>in</strong>g variation <strong>in</strong> non-homestead seizable assets.<br />

Before discuss<strong>in</strong>g the eighth column, I return to Panels E <strong>and</strong> F of Figure 1.9.<br />

These panels show reduced form plots of <strong>in</strong>surance coverage aga<strong>in</strong>st log seizable home<br />

equity under <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted 1920 homestead exemption laws averaged by state.<br />

The historical <strong>in</strong>strument plots show a similar upward-slop<strong>in</strong>g relationship <strong>and</strong> are<br />

somewhat less noisy than the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument plots <strong>in</strong> the row above. One reason<br />

for this is that the New Engl<strong>and</strong> states—which are outliers <strong>in</strong> Panels C <strong>and</strong> D—have<br />

greater seizable assets levels under the historical exemptions <strong>and</strong> are closer to the<br />

regression l<strong>in</strong>e.<br />

Column 8 of Table 1.4 shows the 2SLS estimates with the historical <strong>in</strong>strument.<br />

With the historical <strong>in</strong>strument, the coefficient on log seizable assets is slightly larger<br />

than the preferred estimate (6.39 versus 5.43). A Hausman test cannot reject the va-<br />

lidity of the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument. Given that the historical <strong>in</strong>strument has lower power<br />

<strong>in</strong> the first stage, it seems prudent to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument parameter of<br />

5.43 as the preferred estimate.<br />

1.5.4 Heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> the Effect on Coverage<br />

Table 1.5 exam<strong>in</strong>es heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> the coefficient on log seizable assets by estimat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the preferred specification on subsamples of the data. The 2SLS estimate is somewhat<br />

larger when estimated on the sample of younger versus older households (def<strong>in</strong>ed by<br />

a household head younger than 35) <strong>and</strong> the sample of renters versus homeowners.<br />

Households earn<strong>in</strong>g less than the median <strong>in</strong>come are significantly more responsive to<br />

seizable assets levels (8.18 <strong>in</strong> column 5 versus 2.79 <strong>in</strong> column 6). This is consistent with<br />

?, who f<strong>in</strong>d that low <strong>in</strong>come households are more premium elastic <strong>in</strong> their dem<strong>and</strong> for<br />

health <strong>in</strong>surance. The coefficient on log seizable assets is larger for households with<br />

seizable assets below the median value (8.24 <strong>in</strong> column 7 versus 4.87 <strong>in</strong> column 8).


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 25<br />

1.5.5 The Effect on Wealth <strong>and</strong> Premiums<br />

Table 1.3 showed that <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g controls for wealth <strong>and</strong> premiums did not have much<br />

of an effect on the parameter of <strong>in</strong>terest. Tables 1.6 <strong>and</strong> 1.7 exam<strong>in</strong>e the effects of<br />

asset exemption law on these variables on their own.<br />

Table 1.6 shows OLS <strong>and</strong> 2SLS estimates of assets on state-level measures of asset<br />

exemption law (the <strong>in</strong>struments). Columns 1 to 6 exam<strong>in</strong>e the effects of exemptions<br />

for specific asset categories (home equity <strong>and</strong> vehicle equity). In these specifications,<br />

the dependent variable is an <strong>in</strong>dicator for positive assets or the log asset value. All<br />

specifications <strong>in</strong>clude households controls—<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g a fourth-order polynomial <strong>in</strong><br />

wealth—<strong>and</strong> the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument to control for the overall generosity of asset<br />

exemption laws <strong>in</strong> that state. Columns 1 <strong>and</strong> 2 show estimates of home equity on the<br />

measure of homestead exemptions laws. Columns 3 <strong>and</strong> 4 show similar specifications<br />

with homestead exemptions from 1920 used as an <strong>in</strong>strument. Columns 5 <strong>and</strong> 6 show<br />

estimates with a measure of vehicle equity as the dependent variable. None of the<br />

specifications show a statistically significant relationship between asset exemption<br />

laws <strong>and</strong> assets.<br />

Columns 7 <strong>and</strong> 8 of Table 1.6 exam<strong>in</strong>e the effect of asset exemption law on overall<br />

wealth. In these specifications, the dependent variable is an <strong>in</strong>dicator for positive<br />

wealth or the log wealth value. The parameter on the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument—which<br />

is simply a measure of the generosity of asset exemption laws—is the coefficient of<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest. The specifications <strong>in</strong>clude the st<strong>and</strong>ard set of demographic controls except<br />

for the polynomial <strong>in</strong> wealth. Like the estimates for specific asset categories, there is<br />

no evidence of relationship between asset exemption laws <strong>and</strong> wealth levels.<br />

Table 1.7 exam<strong>in</strong>es the effect of asset exemption law on health <strong>in</strong>surance premi-<br />

ums by show<strong>in</strong>g estimates of log premiums on the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument. Observations<br />

<strong>in</strong> these regressions are monthly premiums for a 30-year-old non-smok<strong>in</strong>g male. All<br />

specifications <strong>in</strong>clude plan fixed effects so that the parameters are identified off dif-<br />

ferences <strong>in</strong> premiums for the same <strong>in</strong>surance product across different states.<br />

The estimates show a marg<strong>in</strong>ally significant, negative relationship between asset<br />

exemption laws <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance premiums, consistent with higher asset exemptions<br />

<strong>in</strong>flat<strong>in</strong>g hospital costs. Columns 1 to 3 show OLS specifications of log premiums


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 26<br />

on the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument. Column 1 has only plan fixed effects. Column 2 adds<br />

state demographic factors. Column 3 <strong>in</strong>cludes controls for state <strong>in</strong>surance market<br />

regulations. The estimates are quite similar across specifications <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicate that a<br />

log po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> seizable assets is associated with a 7 to 10 percent decrease <strong>in</strong><br />

premiums, although the effect is only significantly less than zero at the 10 percent<br />

level. Columns 4 to 6 shows estimates where seizable home equity under 1920 as-<br />

set exemption laws is used as an <strong>in</strong>strument for contemporaneous asset exemptions.<br />

Controls are added analogously to columns 1 to 3. The estimates are slightly more<br />

negative but less precisely estimated. Column 6, which <strong>in</strong>cludes the full set of con-<br />

trols, <strong>in</strong>dicates that a log po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> asset exemptions decreases premiums by<br />

16 percent <strong>and</strong> is significantly negative at the 5 percent level.<br />

1.5.6 Summary <strong>and</strong> Interpretation<br />

Support<strong>in</strong>g the crowd-out prediction, the estimates show a robust positive relationship<br />

between <strong>in</strong>surance coverage <strong>and</strong> seizable assets. The preferred estimate <strong>in</strong>dicates that<br />

a log po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> seizable assets raises <strong>in</strong>surance coverage by 5.43 percentage<br />

po<strong>in</strong>ts. The effect is similar when identified us<strong>in</strong>g variation due to 1920 homestead<br />

exemptions, <strong>and</strong> is stable to the <strong>in</strong>troduction of controls for Census Regions <strong>and</strong><br />

Census Divisions <strong>and</strong> well as relevant state level legislative factors.<br />

There are a number of ways to put this estimate <strong>in</strong> context. Perhaps the most<br />

natural way—given the source of identify<strong>in</strong>g variation—is to consider counterfactuals<br />

<strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g cross-state variation <strong>in</strong> asset exemption law. In the sample, 77.3 percent<br />

of <strong>in</strong>dividuals are <strong>in</strong>sured (recall that the sample excludes the elderly <strong>and</strong> those with<br />

<strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance). If the exemption laws of the most debtor-friendly state (Texas)<br />

were applied nationally, the estimates suggest that the number of un<strong>in</strong>sured would<br />

be <strong>in</strong>creased by 30.0 percent (6.8 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts). 34 If the exemptions laws of<br />

the least debtor-friendly state (Delaware) were applied nationally, 16.3 percent (3.7<br />

percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts) of the un<strong>in</strong>sured would take-up <strong>in</strong>surance. 35 Take-up under the<br />

34 Couples fil<strong>in</strong>g jo<strong>in</strong>tly <strong>in</strong> Texas can exempt all of their home equity, an unlimited amount of<br />

retirement assets, <strong>and</strong> up to $60,000 of any asset of their choose. See Table 1.1 for details.<br />

35 Delaware gives couples fil<strong>in</strong>g jo<strong>in</strong>tly an unlimited exemption for retirement assets <strong>and</strong> a $500


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 27<br />

least debtor-friendly laws is smaller <strong>in</strong> magnitude because most un<strong>in</strong>sured household<br />

have little wealth <strong>and</strong> are thus not exposed to substantially more f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk under<br />

these laws.<br />

Achiev<strong>in</strong>g the same <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> coverage as implied by the Delaware laws would<br />

require a large premium subsidy. Too see this, I use the -0.084 take-up premium<br />

semi-elasticity for the un<strong>in</strong>sured estimated by the ?. 36 With this elasticity, <strong>in</strong>duc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a 3.7 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> coverage requires a premium subsidy of 44.0 (=<br />

100 × (0.037/0.084)) percent.<br />

The effect does not seem to be driven by an endogenous response of either wealth<br />

or premiums. Assets are completely unresponsive to asset exemption laws. And while<br />

a log po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> asset exemptions is associated with a (marg<strong>in</strong>ally significant)<br />

7 percent decrease <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance premiums, controll<strong>in</strong>g for premiums does not impact<br />

the coefficient on seizable assets. This is consistent with f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> the literature<br />

that the dem<strong>and</strong> for health <strong>in</strong>surance is highly premium <strong>in</strong>elastic. For example, with<br />

the -0.084 premium semi-elasticity discussed above, a 7 percent decrease <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

premiums is projected to <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>surance coverage by only 0.6 (=-0.084 × -0.07)<br />

percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts.<br />

1.6 The Effect on Costs<br />

1.6.1 Basel<strong>in</strong>e Estimates<br />

Table 1.8 presents the basel<strong>in</strong>e OLS <strong>and</strong> 2SLS estimates of the effect on costs. The<br />

sample <strong>in</strong>cludes all un<strong>in</strong>sured households with positive medical utilization. St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

errors are clustered at the state level <strong>in</strong> all specifications. In the OLS specification<br />

without controls (column 1), the elasticity of out-of-pocket payments with respect<br />

wildcard exemption. Households cannot exempt any home or vehicle equity <strong>in</strong> excess of the $500<br />

wildcard. See Table 1.1 for details.<br />

36 The ? estimate of -0.084 is identified off premium variation due to state-level community rat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>and</strong> premium compression regulations. The estimate is central to the small number of estimates <strong>in</strong><br />

the literature. It is smaller than the estimate of ?, who use the <strong>in</strong>troduction of a tax subsidy for<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance purchases by the self-employed, <strong>and</strong> is larger than the estimate from ?. See? for a review<br />

of estimates <strong>in</strong> the literature.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 28<br />

to seizable assets is 0.56. Includ<strong>in</strong>g controls for household demographics <strong>and</strong> uti-<br />

lization reduces this coefficient to 0.22 (column 2). Controll<strong>in</strong>g for wealth has little<br />

<strong>in</strong>cremental effect (column 3).<br />

The 2SLS estimates us<strong>in</strong>g the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument are shown <strong>in</strong> columns 4 to 6,<br />

add<strong>in</strong>g controls <strong>in</strong> the same manner as columns 1 to 3. With controls, the 2SLS<br />

po<strong>in</strong>t estimates are slightly larger than the correspond<strong>in</strong>g OLS specifications. In the<br />

preferred specification with controls for demographics <strong>and</strong> utilization (column 5), the<br />

elasticity of out-of-pocket payments with respect to seizable assets is 0.37. As before,<br />

controll<strong>in</strong>g for wealth (column 6) has little effect.<br />

1.6.2 Sensitivity Analysis<br />

Table 1.9 exam<strong>in</strong>es the sensitivity of these results to concerns about potential bias<br />

from endogenous asset exemptions. Column 1 adds controls for hospital <strong>and</strong> state<br />

characteristics. Because hospitals with different ownership structures may have differ-<br />

ent <strong>in</strong>centives <strong>and</strong> preferences for charity care, I <strong>in</strong>clude controls for the share of <strong>public</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> nonprofit hospitals <strong>in</strong> each state (private hospitals are the omitted category). I<br />

control for Disproportionate Share Hospital (DSH) payments per 1,000 residents as<br />

these may affect <strong>in</strong>centives to provide unpaid care, the presence of state charity care<br />

pools, <strong>and</strong> the number of Federally Qualified Health Centers per 100,000 people. The<br />

parameters of <strong>in</strong>terest are virtually unchanged <strong>in</strong> these specifications <strong>and</strong> none of the<br />

covariates have coefficients that are statistically dist<strong>in</strong>guishable from zero.<br />

Column 2 uses the <strong>in</strong>strument that isolates variation due to contemporaneous<br />

homestead exemptions <strong>and</strong> column 3 uses the <strong>in</strong>strument that isolates variation due<br />

to exemptions for non-homestead assets with no effect on the parameter of <strong>in</strong>ter-<br />

est. Column 4 applies the <strong>in</strong>strument that isolates variation due to 1920 homestead<br />

exemptions. Us<strong>in</strong>g this source of variation addresses concerns that contemporane-<br />

ous asset exemptions may be <strong>in</strong>fluenced by unobserved state-level factors such as<br />

the strength of the hospital lobby or state-level attitudes towards charity care. The<br />

estimates are very similar with this <strong>in</strong>strument.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 29<br />

The f<strong>in</strong>al two columns of Table 1.9 exam<strong>in</strong>e heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> the effect by utiliza-<br />

tion level. The capp<strong>in</strong>g-of-cost prediction <strong>and</strong> the simple descriptive evidence shown<br />

<strong>in</strong> Figures 1.2 <strong>and</strong> 1.4 suggest that seizable assets should have a larger impact on<br />

households with high utilization, as the “deductible” of bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance is more<br />

likely to b<strong>in</strong>d for these households. Columns 5 <strong>and</strong> 6 allow the effect to vary by<br />

whether utilization—as measured by the Relative Risk Score—is above the 90th per-<br />

centile (high utilization) or below this level (low utilization). The elasticity parameter<br />

is 0.51 for high utilization <strong>and</strong> about 0.37 for low utilization, consistent with a high<br />

deductible structure for this <strong>in</strong>surance.<br />

1.6.3 Summary <strong>and</strong> Interpretation<br />

Figures 1.2 <strong>and</strong> 1.4 showed that un<strong>in</strong>sured households with fewer seizable assets have<br />

their out-of-pocket payments capped <strong>in</strong> the raw data. The regression estimates show<br />

that this effect is robust to demographic controls <strong>and</strong> variation <strong>in</strong> seizable assets<br />

solely due to cross-state differences <strong>in</strong> asset exemption law. The preferred estimate<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicates that a log po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> seizable assets raises out-of-pocket payments by<br />

37 percent, conditional on medical utilization. Consistent with the high-deductible<br />

structure of this <strong>in</strong>surance, the elasticity is larger for households with high utilization.<br />

1.7 Micro-Simulation Model<br />

To shed light on puzzles <strong>in</strong> the literature <strong>and</strong> exam<strong>in</strong>e policy implications, I calibrate<br />

a micro-simulation model of <strong>in</strong>surance choice. The model is based on the set of un<strong>in</strong>-<br />

sured <strong>and</strong> privately <strong>in</strong>sured households <strong>in</strong> the 2005 PSID. Households face household-<br />

specific medical cost distributions that depend on the age <strong>and</strong> sex of each household<br />

member. Premiums for conventional health <strong>in</strong>surance are based on these costs, scaled<br />

to account for moral hazard, adm<strong>in</strong>istrative costs, <strong>and</strong> the cross-subsidization of un-<br />

paid care to the un<strong>in</strong>sured. Follow<strong>in</strong>g closely the formulation <strong>in</strong> Section 1.2, the model<br />

uses an expected utility framework to implicitly def<strong>in</strong>e each household’s will<strong>in</strong>gness<br />

to pay for conventional health <strong>in</strong>surance. Households purchase coverage if <strong>and</strong> only


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 31<br />

CARA utility. 39 I show results with risk aversion parameters of α =2.5 × 10 −5 (low<br />

risk aversion), α =5.0 × 10 −5 (moderate risk aversion), <strong>and</strong> α =7.5 × 10 −4 (high risk<br />

aversion). Divid<strong>in</strong>g by the median wealth level of $40,318, these parameters can be<br />

<strong>in</strong>terpreted as relative risk coefficients of γ = 1, 2, <strong>and</strong> 3. Household-level medical cost<br />

distributions are constructed us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividual-level medical cost distributions for age-<br />

by-sex-by-<strong>in</strong>surance status cells <strong>in</strong> the 2005 MEPS. The markup for moral hazard<br />

is µ1 = 0.56, the value implied by the RAND health <strong>in</strong>surance experiment price<br />

elasticity of -0.22 <strong>in</strong> an arc elasticity framework (?). The adm<strong>in</strong>istrative load factor<br />

is set to µ2 =0.1 for households with employer sponsored <strong>in</strong>surance <strong>and</strong> µ2 =0.5<br />

for the un<strong>in</strong>sured <strong>and</strong> households <strong>in</strong> the non-group market. 40 I solve for the cross-<br />

subsidization parameter µ3 endogenously us<strong>in</strong>g the cost distributions of un<strong>in</strong>sured<br />

households <strong>in</strong> the model. In Appendix Section 1.10.3, I discuss the construction of<br />

the medical cost distributions <strong>and</strong> premiums <strong>in</strong> more detail. I show that the calibrated<br />

premiums closely match quoted premiums <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dividual market.<br />

1.8 Puzzles <strong>and</strong> Policy<br />

In this section of the paper, I use the micro-simulation model to <strong>in</strong>vestigate how<br />

bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance sheds light on puzzles <strong>in</strong> the health policy literature <strong>and</strong> to<br />

exam<strong>in</strong>e implications of this mechanism for the design of health <strong>in</strong>surance policy.<br />

1.8.1 Puzzles<br />

Puzzle 1: Why are 47 million <strong>in</strong>dividuals un<strong>in</strong>sured?<br />

Expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g why households are un<strong>in</strong>sured is a central puzzle for scholars of health<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance. In his review of the literature ? writes, “there are a variety of hypothe-<br />

ses for why so many <strong>in</strong>dividuals are un<strong>in</strong>sured, but no clear sense that this set of<br />

explanations can account for the 47 million <strong>in</strong>dividuals.” Bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance is a<br />

39 Us<strong>in</strong>g a CARA specification avoids the problems associated with non-positive wealth. Calibrations<br />

with CRRA utility <strong>and</strong> a consumption floor generate stronger results.<br />

40 This values are take from ?.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 32<br />

compell<strong>in</strong>g additional explanation. I used regression analysis to quantify the impor-<br />

tance of this mechanism <strong>in</strong> the sections above. I use the micro-simulation model for<br />

an alternative perspective.<br />

Table 1.10 shows the percent of <strong>in</strong>sured <strong>and</strong> un<strong>in</strong>sured <strong>in</strong>dividuals predicted by<br />

the model to purchase a $2,000 deductible plan. Column 1 shows these predicted<br />

values from a simulation where there is no bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance. Column 2 adds<br />

bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance to the model. Without bankruptcy, <strong>in</strong>sured <strong>and</strong> un<strong>in</strong>sured<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals are difficult to separate. Us<strong>in</strong>g the variation <strong>in</strong> health risk, adm<strong>in</strong>istrative<br />

costs, <strong>and</strong> tax preferences, the model can only separate predicted coverage by 8 to 28<br />

percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts. Because there are large differences <strong>in</strong> seizable assets between these<br />

groups, account<strong>in</strong>g for bankruptcy substantially improves the explanatory power of<br />

the model, exp<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g the gap <strong>in</strong> predicted coverage to 43 to 54 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts.<br />

Bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance thus to <strong>in</strong>creases the gap <strong>in</strong> predicted coverage by 14 to 46<br />

percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts.<br />

Puzzle 2: The low take-up of high deductible plans<br />

A second puzzle is the low take-up of high deductible health plans (HDHP) by the<br />

un<strong>in</strong>sured. HDHPs were <strong>in</strong>tended by their proponents to exp<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance coverage,<br />

yet despite offer<strong>in</strong>g low premiums they have not been successful <strong>in</strong> this regard (?).<br />

Crowd-out from implicit <strong>in</strong>surance is an appeal<strong>in</strong>g explanation for this failure. Be-<br />

cause the median un<strong>in</strong>sured household has less than $5,000 <strong>in</strong> seizable assets, HDHPs<br />

are largely redundant to the implicit <strong>in</strong>surance they already hold. Figure 1.10 makes<br />

this case quantitatively, plott<strong>in</strong>g the percent of un<strong>in</strong>sured households projected to<br />

purchase <strong>in</strong>surance by deductible level. Without bankruptcy, the probability of pur-<br />

chase <strong>in</strong>creases sharply from 19 percent for a $1,000 deductible plan to 43 percent for<br />

a $5,000 deductible plan, as the concavity of utility makes <strong>in</strong>surance more valuable at<br />

higher deductible levels. With bankruptcy, this <strong>in</strong>crease is virtually elim<strong>in</strong>ated, ris<strong>in</strong>g<br />

from 2 percent for a $1,000 deductible plan to only 6 percent for a $5,000 deductible<br />

contract, a full 37 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts below the projected value without bankruptcy.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 33<br />

Puzzle 3: Ris<strong>in</strong>g risk, fall<strong>in</strong>g coverage<br />

A third puzzle is the association between ris<strong>in</strong>g health <strong>in</strong>surance costs <strong>and</strong> fall<strong>in</strong>g cov-<br />

erage. ? show that more than half the decrease <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance coverage over the 1990s<br />

can be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by ris<strong>in</strong>g premiums. Yet as the authors expla<strong>in</strong>, from the st<strong>and</strong>po<strong>in</strong>t<br />

of economic theory this is counter<strong>in</strong>tuitive. With st<strong>and</strong>ard risk preferences, ris<strong>in</strong>g un-<br />

derly<strong>in</strong>g costs should lead to <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>surance coverage. Tak<strong>in</strong>g bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>to<br />

account, however, reverses this <strong>in</strong>tuition. The decrease <strong>in</strong> coverage can be expla<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

by households substitut<strong>in</strong>g conventional health <strong>in</strong>surance for bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

that is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> actuarial value without <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> price.<br />

Puzzle 4: The <strong>in</strong>surance generosity gap<br />

A fourth puzzle is the <strong>in</strong>surance generosity gap. In his review of the literature, ? asks<br />

why most U.S. households appear to be either under-<strong>in</strong>sured or over-<strong>in</strong>sured but rarely<br />

<strong>in</strong>-between. Implicit <strong>in</strong>surance from bankruptcy can expla<strong>in</strong> this f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g. To illustrate<br />

how bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance creates a generosity gap, Figure 1.11 presents a stylized<br />

budget set. Without bankruptcy, households face the st<strong>and</strong>ard cont<strong>in</strong>uous tradeoff<br />

between <strong>in</strong>surance generosity (y-axis) <strong>and</strong> other goods (x-axis). Implicit <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

generates a notch: households receive some implicit <strong>in</strong>surance without giv<strong>in</strong>g up other<br />

goods. Convex preferences give rise to an <strong>in</strong>surance generosity gap, with households<br />

sort<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to the more generous conventional health <strong>in</strong>surance <strong>and</strong> the less generous<br />

implicit <strong>in</strong>surance from bankruptcy.<br />

1.8.2 Policy Implications<br />

I use the micro-simulation model to exam<strong>in</strong>e welfare implications of this mechanism.<br />

From a policy design perspective, bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance has many potential draw-<br />

backs: It forces the un<strong>in</strong>sured to receive care <strong>in</strong> emergency rooms, which are often<br />

not the most appropriate sett<strong>in</strong>gs (?), <strong>and</strong> may lead to <strong>in</strong>efficiently low levels of<br />

preventative care, <strong>in</strong>flat<strong>in</strong>g overall costs (?). Negotiation under the threat-po<strong>in</strong>t of<br />

bankruptcy is probably not the most efficient way of process<strong>in</strong>g payments <strong>and</strong> there<br />

are deadweight costs <strong>and</strong> externalities to formal bankruptcy.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 34<br />

For this exercise, however, I focus on a s<strong>in</strong>gle problem: because bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>sur-<br />

ance has a price of zero but cross-subsidized costs, too many households choose to be<br />

un<strong>in</strong>sured. I f<strong>in</strong>d this <strong>in</strong>efficiency particularly <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g because it directly relates<br />

to the <strong>in</strong>surance coverage decision <strong>and</strong> because the problem is naturally addressed<br />

with penalties for be<strong>in</strong>g un<strong>in</strong>sured—a key <strong>and</strong> controversial element of PPACA. 41<br />

Of course, conventional health <strong>in</strong>surance has well-documented <strong>in</strong>efficiencies as<br />

well. Relative to bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance, moral hazard is particularly relavent. 42 With<br />

conventional health <strong>in</strong>surance it is well known that medical providers <strong>and</strong> patients<br />

often have <strong>in</strong>centives to supply <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> excess medical care. With bankruptcy<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, physicians are more likely to be exposed to the social<br />

cost of their decisions <strong>and</strong> patients have little leverage to dem<strong>and</strong> excess treatment.<br />

Thus, for the optimal “Pigovian penalties,” low moral hazard bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

may be the efficient choice for some households.<br />

Table 1.11 shows the welfare effects of different penalty systems. For each penalty<br />

system, I allow households to choose between conventional <strong>in</strong>surance at the cali-<br />

brated premiums <strong>and</strong> bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance at the cost of the penalty. 43 The results<br />

are shown relative to a basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> which households can choose bankruptcy at no<br />

cost. The first set of rows shows coverage <strong>and</strong> welfare under the optimal Pigovian<br />

penalties—def<strong>in</strong>ed as the household-specific actuarially fair cost of the implicit <strong>in</strong>sur-<br />

ance from bankruptcy. 44 The optimal penalties average $218 per person <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>duce<br />

7 to 8 percent of the un<strong>in</strong>sured to take-up coverage. As <strong>in</strong>dicated by the higher<br />

will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay, these households purchase more generous coverage than they had<br />

from bankruptcy. Due to the <strong>in</strong>creased moral hazard, however, costs rise by almost<br />

as much. The net effect is an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> surplus of only $4 to $5 per person.<br />

The second panel shows the welfare effects of the PPACA penalty system. When<br />

fully implemented <strong>in</strong> 2016, these penalties will equal the greater of $625 or 2.5 percent<br />

41For this exercise, I assume that un<strong>in</strong>sured households are not already subsidized through the<br />

tax code or some other channel.<br />

42Empirically, adverse selection does not seem to affect <strong>in</strong>surance choice on the extensive marg<strong>in</strong><br />

(??).<br />

43Recall that calibrated premiums are calculated us<strong>in</strong>g costs scaled up for moral hazard, adm<strong>in</strong>istrative<br />

load<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong> the cross-subsidization of the un<strong>in</strong>sured.<br />

44That is, expected medical costs above seizable assets.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 35<br />

of <strong>in</strong>come per household, up to a maximum of $2,085. Under these penalties, deflated<br />

to 2005 levels assum<strong>in</strong>g trend <strong>in</strong>flation, take-up ranges from 50 to 64 percent. The<br />

generosity of coverage does not change much on average while—due to higher moral<br />

hazard—costs <strong>in</strong>crease by a significant amount. The net effect is a decrease <strong>in</strong> surplus<br />

of $9 to $13 per person.<br />

The third panel considers the welfare effects of prevent<strong>in</strong>g households from dis-<br />

charg<strong>in</strong>g medical debt <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy—the exact exercise performed <strong>in</strong> coverage <strong>and</strong><br />

cost counterfactuals. Without bankruptcy, all households purchase conventional <strong>in</strong>-<br />

surance. As <strong>in</strong>dicated by the lower will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay, these plans are less generous<br />

on average. Because of the higher moral hazard from conventional <strong>in</strong>surance, costs<br />

do not shr<strong>in</strong>k by a commensurate amount. The net effect is a reduction <strong>in</strong> surplus<br />

of $36 to $43 per person. While the exact numbers, of course, are a function of the<br />

particular calibration parameters, the takeaway po<strong>in</strong>t from this last exercise is a sim-<br />

ple message: despite <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>surance coverage, elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

may not be socially desirable.<br />

1.9 Conclusion<br />

Underst<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g why households choose health <strong>in</strong>surance is fundamental to positive <strong>and</strong><br />

normative analysis of health <strong>in</strong>surance policy—yet the <strong>in</strong>surance coverage decision is<br />

not well understood. The objective of this paper is to describe <strong>and</strong> evaluate how the<br />

implicit <strong>in</strong>surance from bankruptcy bears on this decision. In the first part of the<br />

paper, I argued that the fact that most medical care is provided on credit coupled<br />

with the ability of households to discharge this debt for seizable assets <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy<br />

provides households with a form of high-deducible health <strong>in</strong>surance.<br />

I next evaluated the quantitative significance of this bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>surance. Ex-<br />

ploit<strong>in</strong>g variation <strong>in</strong> seizable assets that is orthogonal to wealth <strong>and</strong> other household<br />

characteristics, I found that households with more seizable assets make higher out-<br />

of-pocket payments <strong>and</strong> are substantially more likely to be <strong>in</strong>sured. The estimates<br />

suggest that if medical debt could not be discharged <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy, 16.3 percent<br />

of the un<strong>in</strong>sured would purchase coverage. Achiev<strong>in</strong>g the same <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> coverage


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 38<br />

education loans. While the PSID <strong>and</strong> MEPS dist<strong>in</strong>guish rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> vehi-<br />

cle pr<strong>in</strong>ciple from other debts, these other debts are not further decomposed. 45 The<br />

lead<strong>in</strong>g potential concern is that these other debts <strong>in</strong>clude a substantial amount of<br />

education debt—particularly for households with recent college graduates who may<br />

also be on the marg<strong>in</strong> of <strong>in</strong>surance coverage. To overcome this issue, I estimate the<br />

share of education debt <strong>in</strong> total unsecured debt <strong>in</strong> the 2004 Survey of Consumer<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ances (SCF) <strong>and</strong> use this estimate to project education debt <strong>in</strong> the PSID <strong>and</strong><br />

MEPS. In particular, I use parameter estimates from a probit regression of the share<br />

of education debt <strong>in</strong> total unsecured debt on <strong>in</strong>come, family structure, age of the<br />

household head, <strong>and</strong> unsecured debt level fully <strong>in</strong>teracted with a categorical variable<br />

for educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment of the head to project education debt values.<br />

1.10.3 Micro-Simulation Details<br />

Medical Cost Distributions<br />

I construct the household-level medical cost distributions us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividual-level med-<br />

ical cost data from the 2005 MEPS for age-by-sex-by-<strong>in</strong>surance status cells. 46 For<br />

<strong>in</strong>sured <strong>in</strong>dividuals, costs are def<strong>in</strong>ed as total payments. For un<strong>in</strong>sured <strong>in</strong>dividu-<br />

als, my measure of costs <strong>in</strong> construct <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g way: I start with medical<br />

charges as this variable accounts for medical services written off as charity care or<br />

bad debt. I then scale down charges by the cost-charge ratio (CCR) for the privately<br />

<strong>in</strong>sured population to account for the discount typically extended to the un<strong>in</strong>sured. 47<br />

45 The debt variable <strong>in</strong> the PSID is based on the question “Aside from the debts that we have<br />

already talked about, like any mortgage on your ma<strong>in</strong> or vehicle loans – do [you/you or anyone <strong>in</strong><br />

your family] currently have any other debts such as credit card charges, student loans, medical or<br />

legal bills, or loans from relatives?” In the MEPS it is based on the question “Does anyone <strong>in</strong> the<br />

family have any debts that we haven’t asked about, such as credit card balances, medical debts,<br />

life <strong>in</strong>surance policy loans, loans from relatives, <strong>and</strong> so forth?” While both these variables may<br />

<strong>in</strong>clude additional non-dischargeable debt (e.g., department store loans collateralized by durable<br />

goods, unpaid taxes), the bias <strong>in</strong>troduced by this is likely to be small.<br />

46 The age-by-sex groups are no more than 18 years old, male age 19 to 34, female age 19 to 34,<br />

male age 35 to 64, <strong>and</strong> female age 35 to 64.<br />

47 Recall from Figure 1.2 that privately <strong>in</strong>sured <strong>and</strong> un<strong>in</strong>sured households make similar payments<br />

for low charges.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 40<br />

TaxSim program.<br />

Appendix Table 1.15 shows the result<strong>in</strong>g distributions of medical costs <strong>and</strong> pre-<br />

miums normalized by household size for comparison. Costs have a long right tail:<br />

while 91 percent of persons <strong>in</strong>cur less than $1,000 <strong>in</strong> a given year, about 1 <strong>in</strong> 36 <strong>in</strong>cur<br />

more than $5,000 <strong>and</strong> 1 <strong>in</strong> 69 <strong>in</strong>cur more than $10,000 <strong>in</strong> medical costs. Calibrated<br />

premiums drop steeply from $2,126 per person for a plan with first dollar coverage to<br />

$1,009 per person for a $10,000 deductible plan.<br />

As a reality check, Appendix Table 1.15 compares these premiums to quoted<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividual market premiums for the median un<strong>in</strong>sured <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong> the data (a 32-<br />

year-old male), adjusted for <strong>in</strong>flation <strong>and</strong> cost-shar<strong>in</strong>g. 48 The calibrated <strong>and</strong> market<br />

premiums are quite similar. The calibrated premiums are slightly less expensive<br />

for low deductible levels <strong>and</strong> somewhat more expensive for high deductibles. This<br />

difference could be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by selection or by heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> the moral hazard<br />

parameter across the expenditure distribution.<br />

48 The <strong>in</strong>dividual market premiums, from www.ehealth<strong>in</strong>surance.com, are for a non-smok<strong>in</strong>g 32year-old<br />

male. The policies are issued by Aetna <strong>and</strong> start <strong>in</strong> May 2010. They are adjusted for<br />

<strong>in</strong>flation us<strong>in</strong>g the Medical Care component of the CPI-U.


Percent by <strong>in</strong>surance status<br />

CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 41<br />

70%<br />

60%<br />

50%<br />

40%<br />

30%<br />

20%<br />

10%<br />

0%<br />

Figure 1.1: Histogram of Seizable Assets by Insurance Status<br />


Payments<br />

CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 42<br />

$35,000<br />

$30,000<br />

$25,000<br />

$20,000<br />

$15,000<br />

$10,000<br />

$5,000<br />

$-<br />

Figure 1.2: Payments vs. Charges by Insurance Status<br />

Privately <strong>in</strong>sured<br />

Un<strong>in</strong>sured<br />

$- $10,000 $20,000 $30,000 $40,000 $50,000 $60,000 $70,000 $80,000<br />

Charges<br />

Notes: Payments versus medical charges for un<strong>in</strong>sured <strong>and</strong> private <strong>in</strong>sured households.<br />

Payments are the sum of out-of-pocket payments <strong>and</strong> payments from private <strong>in</strong>surers. The<br />

plot is created by averag<strong>in</strong>g payments <strong>and</strong> charges at 20ths of the charge distribution.<br />

Pooled 2000 to 2005 MEPS, <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U. Excludes<br />

households with a head age 65 or older. Household-level estimates weighted by number of<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals per household for <strong>in</strong>terpretation at the <strong>in</strong>dividual level.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 43<br />

Figure 1.3: Provider Bill<strong>in</strong>g Decision: Submitted Bill vs. List Price of Medical Care<br />

s (submitted bill)<br />

w S (seizable assets)<br />

Formal bankruptcy<br />

m (list price of medical care)<br />

s = m<br />

s̅(ŵ S )<br />

Informal bankruptcy<br />

s̅(ŵ S )


OOP payments<br />

CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 44<br />

$9,000<br />

$8,000<br />

$7,000<br />

$6,000<br />

$5,000<br />

$4,000<br />

$3,000<br />

$2,000<br />

$1,000<br />

$-<br />

Figure 1.4: Payments vs. Charges by Seizable Assets<br />

wS ! $50,000<br />

$10,000 " wS < $50,000<br />

wS< $10,000<br />

$- $5,000 $10,000 $15,000 $20,000 $25,000 $30,000 $35,000 $40,000 $45,000<br />

Charges<br />

Notes: Out-of-pocket payments versus medical charges for un<strong>in</strong>sured households with low<br />

(¡ $10,000), moderate ($10,000 to $50,000), <strong>and</strong> high (≥ $50,000) levels of seizable assets.<br />

The plot is created by averag<strong>in</strong>g payments <strong>and</strong> charges at 20ths of the charge distribution.<br />

Pooled 2000 to 2005 MEPS, <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U. Excludes<br />

households with a head age 65 or older. Household-level estimates weighted by number of<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals per household for <strong>in</strong>terpretation at the <strong>in</strong>dividual level.


Simulated <strong>in</strong>strument<br />

CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 45<br />

11<br />

10.5<br />

10<br />

9.5<br />

9<br />

8.5<br />

8<br />

Figure 1.5: Simulated Instrument by State<br />

DE PANJMIOHSCNELAALKYTNWYILMONCUTHIINNYMDGAORWAIDCACONMWIVAMANDCTARMTAKIAFLMNOKAZSDWVMSMEVTNHRINVKSDCTX<br />

States<br />

Notes: The simulated <strong>in</strong>strument is log seizable assets for a constant, nationally<br />

representative sample of households as though they lived <strong>in</strong> each state. The sample is<br />

made up of un<strong>in</strong>sured <strong>and</strong> privately <strong>in</strong>sured households, exclud<strong>in</strong>g households with a head<br />

age 65 or older. Pooled 1999 to 2005 PSID, <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.<br />

See text for details on the seizable assets calculation.


ln(seizable sssets)<br />

CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 46<br />

Figure 1.6: Log Seizable Assets Percentiles by State for a Constant Sample of Households<br />

11.5<br />

11<br />

10.5<br />

10<br />

9.5<br />

9<br />

8.5<br />

8<br />

7.5<br />

DE PANJMISCOHNEALTNKYINILMOMDWYNCLAGANYUTVAHIORWAWIIDNMCACONDAKWVCTIAMAARMTFLSDMNOKAZMSMEVTNHRINVKSDCTX<br />

Notes: Percentiles of log seizable assets for a constant, nationally representative sample of<br />

households as though they lived <strong>in</strong> each state. The sample is made up of un<strong>in</strong>sured <strong>and</strong><br />

privately <strong>in</strong>sured households, exclud<strong>in</strong>g households with a head age 65 or older. Pooled<br />

1999 to 2005 PSID, <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U. See text for details on the<br />

seizable assets calculation.<br />

State<br />

50th<br />

40th<br />

30th<br />

20th


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 47<br />

Figure 1.7: Seizable Homestead Equity <strong>in</strong> 2005 vs. 1920 for a Constant Sample of<br />

Households<br />

Seizable home equity <strong>in</strong> 2005<br />

0 20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000<br />

Slope = 1.96 (0.38)<br />

R-squared = 0.42<br />

ID<br />

CA<br />

NV<br />

TX<br />

AZ<br />

MS<br />

AR<br />

AL<br />

NE<br />

LA<br />

CO<br />

MI<br />

GA<br />

MO<br />

40,000 50,000 60,000 70,000 80,000<br />

Seizable home equity <strong>in</strong> 1920<br />

Notes: Mean seizable home equity for a constant, nationally representative sample of<br />

households under 2005 <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted 1920 homestead exemption laws as they<br />

lived <strong>in</strong> each state. The New Engl<strong>and</strong> states are shaded red. The sample is made up of<br />

un<strong>in</strong>sured <strong>and</strong> privately <strong>in</strong>sured households, exclud<strong>in</strong>g households with a head age 65 or<br />

older. Slope coefficient from a bivariate regression weighted by population, with a robust<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard error <strong>in</strong> parentheses. Pooled 1999 to 2005 PSID, <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the CPI-U. States that did not exist or had acre-based homestead exemption laws are<br />

excluded. Household-level estimates weighted by number of <strong>in</strong>dividuals per household for<br />

<strong>in</strong>terpretation at the <strong>in</strong>dividual level.<br />

WY<br />

VA<br />

UT<br />

WV<br />

KY OH SC<br />

NC IL<br />

NY NJ<br />

TN<br />

WA<br />

NM<br />

CT<br />

MA<br />

IN<br />

ME<br />

VT<br />

NH<br />

PA<br />

MD DE<br />

RI


50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Insurance coverage (percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts)<br />

Figure 1.8: Insurance Coverage vs. Seizable Assets<br />

ND<br />

ME<br />

MT<br />

VT<br />

MN<br />

CT<br />

MA<br />

AK<br />

AL<br />

AR AZ<br />

IA PA<br />

DC<br />

MS<br />

DE<br />

KS<br />

OK<br />

WI NY KY<br />

TN MO<br />

GA ID<br />

CO IL<br />

VA NMUT NV MD MI<br />

NH<br />

NC OH<br />

OR<br />

NE HI<br />

SC<br />

FL<br />

IN<br />

SD<br />

CA<br />

WA<br />

TX<br />

WY LA<br />

WV<br />

8 9 10 11 12<br />

ln(seizable assets)<br />

(a) Insurance Coverage vs. Seizable<br />

Assets<br />

60 70 80 90 100<br />

Insurance coverage (percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts)<br />

TX<br />

MT<br />

VT<br />

RI<br />

CT<br />

ND MA<br />

ME<br />

MN<br />

NJ<br />

IA<br />

DC<br />

NH<br />

NV<br />

KS<br />

NY TN<br />

WI WA ID<br />

KY<br />

AK<br />

GA IL<br />

NM<br />

CO MD<br />

MO<br />

VA OR UT<br />

OH<br />

NC NE<br />

FL<br />

HI<br />

IN<br />

SC<br />

AL<br />

AZ<br />

AR<br />

PA<br />

MI<br />

SD<br />

MS OK<br />

WV<br />

8.5 9 9.5 10 10.5<br />

ln(seizable assets) for constant sample<br />

(c) Insurance Coverage vs. Simulated<br />

Instrument<br />

60 70 80 90 100<br />

Insurance coverage (percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts)<br />

ID<br />

NV<br />

GAMI<br />

MO<br />

CO VAUT<br />

NE<br />

NY TN<br />

KY WA IL<br />

NM<br />

OH<br />

NC<br />

SC<br />

PA<br />

NH<br />

IN<br />

MD<br />

AZ<br />

AR<br />

AL<br />

CA<br />

TX<br />

MS<br />

WY<br />

8.6 8.8 9 9.2 9.4 9.6<br />

ln(seizable home equity) for constant sample<br />

(e) Insurance Coverage vs. Historical<br />

Instrument<br />

LA<br />

CA<br />

RI<br />

CT<br />

NJ<br />

WV<br />

MA<br />

WY<br />

NJ<br />

ME<br />

LA<br />

VT<br />

DE<br />

DE<br />

RI<br />

50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Insurance coverage (percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts)<br />

8 9 10 11 12<br />

ln(seizable assets)<br />

(b) Insurance Coverage vs. Seizable<br />

Assets<br />

60 70 80 90 100<br />

Insurance coverage (percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts)<br />

8.5 9 9.5 10 10.5<br />

ln(seizable assets) for constant saple<br />

(d) Insurance Coverage vs. Simulated<br />

Instrument<br />

60 70 80 90 100<br />

Insurance coverage (percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts)<br />

8.6 8.8 9 9.2 9.4 9.6<br />

ln(seizable home equity) for constant sample<br />

(f) Insurance Coverage vs. Historical<br />

Instrument<br />

Notes: Figures on the same row show the exact same data. In the left column, data po<strong>in</strong>ts<br />

are <strong>in</strong>dicated with state abbreviations. In the right column, states are <strong>in</strong>dicated with<br />

circles proportional to the number of observations from that state. Panels A <strong>and</strong> B plot<br />

the raw data: <strong>in</strong>surance coverage aga<strong>in</strong>st log seizable assets averaged by state. Panels C<br />

<strong>and</strong> D plots the reduced form: <strong>in</strong>surance coverage aga<strong>in</strong>st the <strong>in</strong>strument by state. The<br />

simulated <strong>in</strong>strument is mean log seizable assets for a constant, nationally representative<br />

sample of households as though they lived <strong>in</strong> that state. Panels E <strong>and</strong> F plots the reduced<br />

form with the historical <strong>in</strong>strument. The historical <strong>in</strong>strument is constructed similarly to<br />

the simulated <strong>in</strong>strument us<strong>in</strong>g seizable home equity under <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted 1920<br />

homestead exemption laws. The sample is made up of un<strong>in</strong>sured <strong>and</strong> privately <strong>in</strong>sured<br />

households, exclud<strong>in</strong>g households with a head age 65 or older. Pooled data from the 1999<br />

to 2005 PSID, <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 49<br />

Coefficient on ln(seizable assets)<br />

9<br />

8<br />

7<br />

6<br />

5<br />

4<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

0<br />

Figure 1.9: Effect on Coverage on Samples Exclud<strong>in</strong>g Each State<br />

AK ALARAZCACOCTDCDEFLGAHIIAIDILINKSKYLAMAMDMEMIMNMOMSMTNCNDNENHNJNMNVNYOHOKORPARISCSDTNTXUTVAVTWAWIWVWY<br />

Excluded state<br />

Notes: Figure shows the coefficients <strong>and</strong> 95 percent confidence <strong>in</strong>tervals from the basel<strong>in</strong>e<br />

2SLS specification exclud<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>dicated state. The specification is the same as column<br />

6 of Table 1.3. The 95 percent confidence <strong>in</strong>tervals are constructed us<strong>in</strong>g robust st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

errors clustered at the state level. See the Table 1.3 note for more details.


Pr(WTP > premium)<br />

CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 50<br />

Figure 1.10: Micro-Simulation Estimates of Percent Covered Without <strong>and</strong> With<br />

Bankruptcy Insurance by Deductible<br />

70%<br />

60%<br />

50%<br />

40%<br />

30%<br />

20%<br />

10%<br />

0%<br />

Pr(WTP without > premium)<br />

Pr(WTP with > premium)<br />

$- $1,000 $2,000 $3,000 $4,000 $5,000 $6,000 $7,000 $8,000<br />

Deductible<br />

Notes: Micro-simulation estimates of the probability the will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay (WTP)<br />

exceeds the premium without <strong>and</strong> with bankruptcy by deductible level. Will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay<br />

is calculated us<strong>in</strong>g CARA utility with parameter of 2.5 × 10 −5 . Premiums calculated as<br />

the expected value of medical costs above the deductible scaled up to account for moral<br />

hazard (elasticity of -0.22) <strong>and</strong> adm<strong>in</strong>istrative load<strong>in</strong>g (50 percent). Household-level<br />

estimates weighted by number of <strong>in</strong>dividuals per household for <strong>in</strong>terpretation at the<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividual level.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 51<br />

Insurance generosity<br />

Generosity gap<br />

Figure 1.11: The Insurance Generosity Gap<br />

Conventional <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

Other goods<br />

Implicit <strong>in</strong>surance


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 52<br />

Table 1.1: Asset Exemption Laws by State<br />

Contemporaneous exemptions Homestead<br />

Other<br />

exemptions<br />

f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

Wildcard no Federal for town lots<br />

State Homestead Vehicle Retirement assets Wildcard homestead available <strong>in</strong> 1920<br />

Alabama 10,000 0 Unlimited 0 6,000 6,000 No 2,000<br />

Alaska 67,500 7,500 Unlimited 3,500 0 0 No n/a<br />

Arizona 150,000 10,000 Unlimited 300 0 0 No 4,000<br />

Arkansas Unlimited 2,400 40,000 0 500 500 Yes 2,500<br />

California--system 1 75,000 4,600 Unlimited 1,825 0 0 No 5,000<br />

California--system 2 0 2,975 Unlimited 0 19,675 19,675 No n/a<br />

Colorado 90,000 6,000 Unlimited 0 0 0 No 2,000<br />

Connecticut 150,000 3,000 Unlimited 0 2,000 2,000 Yes 1,000<br />

Delaware 0 0 Unlimited 0 500 500 No 0<br />

District of Columbia Unlimited 5,150 Unlimited 0 17,850 17,850 Yes n/a<br />

Florida Unlimited 2,000 Unlimited 0 2,000 2,000 No n/a<br />

Georgia 10,000 7,000 Unlimited 0 11,200 11,200 No 1,600<br />

Hawaii 40,000 5,150 Unlimited 0 0 0 Yes n/a<br />

Idaho 50,000 6,000 Unlimited 0 1,600 1,600 No 5,000<br />

Ill<strong>in</strong>ois 15,000 2,400 Unlimited 0 4,000 4,000 No 1,000<br />

Indiana 0 0 Unlimited 0 20,000 20,000 No 600<br />

Iowa Unlimited 1,000 Unlimited 0 200 200 No n/a<br />

Kansas Unlimited 40,000 Unlimited 0 0 0 No n/a<br />

Kentucky 10,000 5,000 Unlimited 0 2,000 2,000 No 1,000<br />

Louisiana 25,000 0 Unlimited 0 0 0 No 2,000<br />

Ma<strong>in</strong>e 70,000 10,000 Unlimited 0 12,800 12,800 No 500<br />

Maryl<strong>and</strong> 0 0 Unlimited 0 22,000 22,000 No 0<br />

Massachusetts 1,000,000 1,400 Unlimited 1,250 0 0 Yes 800<br />

Michigan 7,000 0 Unlimited 0 0 0 No 1,500<br />

M<strong>in</strong>nesota 200,000 7,600 Unlimited 0 0 0 Yes n/a<br />

Mississippi 150,000 0 Unlimited 0 10,000 10,000 No 3,000<br />

Missouri 15,000 6,000 Unlimited 0 1,250 1,250 No 1,500<br />

Montana 200,000 5,000 Unlimited 0 0 0 No n/a<br />

Nebraska 12,500 0 Unlimited 0 0 5,000 No 2,000<br />

Nevada 400,000 30,000 1,000,000 0 0 0 No 5,000<br />

New Hampshire 200,000 8,000 Unlimited 0 8,000 8,000 Yes 500<br />

New Jersey 0 0 Unlimited 0 2,000 2,000 Yes 1,000<br />

New Mexico 60,000 8,000 Unlimited 0 1,000 4,000 Yes 1,000<br />

New York 20,000 0 Unlimited 0 10,000 10,000 No 1,000<br />

North Carol<strong>in</strong>a 13,000 3,000 Unlimited 0 8,000 8,000 No 1,000<br />

North Dakota 80,000 2,400 200,000 0 0 15,000 No n/a<br />

Ohio 10,000 2,000 Unlimited 800 800 800 No 1,000<br />

Oklahoma Unlimited 6,000 Unlimited 0 0 0 No n/a<br />

Oregon 33,000 3,400 15,000 15,000 800 800 No n/a<br />

Pennsylvania 0 0 Unlimited 0 600 600 Yes 300<br />

Rhode Isl<strong>and</strong> 200,000 20,000 Unlimited 0 0 0 Yes 0<br />

South Carol<strong>in</strong>a 10,000 2,400 Unlimited 0 0 2,000 No 1,000<br />

South Dakota Unlimited 0 500,000 0 4,000 4,000 No n/a<br />

Tennessee 7,500 0 Unlimited 0 8,000 8,000 No 1,000<br />

Texas Unlimited 0 Unlimited 0 60,000 60,000 Yes 5,000<br />

Utah 40,000 5,000 Unlimited 0 0 0 No 2,000<br />

Vermont 150,000 5,000 Unlimited 1,400 8,400 8,400 Yes 2,000<br />

Virg<strong>in</strong>ia 0 4,000 35,000 0 32,000 32,000 No 500<br />

Wash<strong>in</strong>gton 40,000 5,000 Unlimited 0 4,000 4,000 Yes 1,000<br />

West Virg<strong>in</strong>ia 0 4,800 Unlimited 0 51,600 51,600 No 1,000<br />

Wiscons<strong>in</strong> 40,000 0 Unlimited 2,000 10,000 10,000 Yes n/a<br />

Wyom<strong>in</strong>g 20,000 4,800 Unlimited 0 0 0 No 2,500<br />

Federal 18,500 5,900 Unlimited 0 20,450 20,450 n/a n/a<br />

Averages* 58,821 4,884 298,333 501 6,592 7,073 27% 1,679<br />

Notes: Contemporaneous exemptions for couples fil<strong>in</strong>g jo<strong>in</strong>tly from Elias (2007) <strong>and</strong> historical exemptions for couples fil<strong>in</strong>g jo<strong>in</strong>tly<br />

from Goodman (1993). Under contemporaneous law, California residents can choose between system 1 <strong>and</strong> 2 <strong>and</strong> residents can<br />

choose federal exemptions <strong>in</strong> states where federal exemptions are available. Wildcard no homestead exemption is available to<br />

households which do not take the homestead exemption. For the historical exemptions, states that did not exist <strong>and</strong> states that had<br />

acre-based exemptions are denoted as n/a. States that did not have homestead exemptions are assigned a value of zero.<br />

*Excludes states with unlimited or n/a exemptions.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 53<br />

Table 1.2: Implied First Stage Estimates<br />

Dependent variable: ln(w<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

Instruments<br />

Basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument 1.00<br />

(0.04)<br />

Homestead <strong>in</strong>strument 0.38<br />

(0.06)<br />

Non-homestead <strong>in</strong>strument 1.10<br />

(0.10)<br />

Historical homestead <strong>in</strong>strument<br />

Age group<br />

1.41<br />

(0.31)<br />

35-44 -0.14 -0.14 -0.13 -0.12<br />

(0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02)<br />

45-54 -0.20 -0.20 -0.20 -0.20<br />

(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.04)<br />

55-64 -0.23 -0.23 -0.21 -0.22<br />

Family structure<br />

(0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04)<br />

Couple -0.21 -0.21 -0.20 -0.22<br />

(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03)<br />

S<strong>in</strong>gle parent -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 0.00<br />

(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03)<br />

Couple with children -0.27 -0.26 -0.26 -0.26<br />

Race<br />

(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.04)<br />

Non-white 0.00 -0.01 0.01 0.02<br />

Education<br />

(0.02) (0.03) (0.02) (0.02)<br />

High school to some college 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.05<br />

(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.02)<br />

College or greater -0.01 0.00 0.01 0.01<br />

(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03)<br />

S )<br />

Income polynomial (4th order) Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

State controls Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

R-squared 0.89 0.88 0.88 0.89<br />

N 20,265 20,265 20,265 17,418<br />

F-statistic on excluded <strong>in</strong>strument 494.06 36.16 116.93 20.95<br />

Prob > F 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

Notes: The basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument is mean log seizable assets for a constant, nationally representative sample of households<br />

as though they lived <strong>in</strong> that state. The homestead, non-homestead, <strong>and</strong> historical homestead <strong>in</strong>struments are constructed<br />

similarly us<strong>in</strong>g seizable home equity, non-homestead seizable assets, <strong>and</strong> seizable home equity under <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted<br />

1920 homestead exemption laws. The excluded demographic groups are age 18-34, s<strong>in</strong>gle, less than high school, <strong>and</strong><br />

white. The state controls are mean <strong>in</strong>come, percent unemployed, <strong>and</strong> percent covered by Medicaid. Robust st<strong>and</strong>ard errors<br />

clustered at the state level <strong>in</strong> parentheses. Pooled 1999 to 2005 PSID exclud<strong>in</strong>g households with <strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance or a head<br />

age 65 or older. Inflation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 54<br />

Table 1.3: Basel<strong>in</strong>e Coverage Estimates<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)<br />

ln(w S Dependent variable: Percent of household <strong>in</strong>sured<br />

OLS 2SLS<br />

) 6.13 2.45 2.36 2.63 8.80 5.43 5.38 6.15<br />

Age group<br />

(0.37) (0.20) (0.53) (0.25) (2.27) (1.16) (0.95) (0.87)<br />

35-44 4.48 3.98 4.48 3.49 4.28 3.32<br />

(0.97) (0.93) (1.13) (1.10) (0.88) (1.60)<br />

45-54 3.08 2.48 2.91 1.22 2.94 0.78<br />

(1.04) (1.02) (1.34) (1.27) (0.98) (2.39)<br />

55-64 8.03 7.44 8.48 4.53 7.79 4.42<br />

Family structure<br />

(1.08) (1.05) (1.44) (1.81) (1.01) (3.63)<br />

Couple 5.38 4.76 6.55 5.05 5.29 5.89<br />

(1.55) (1.43) (1.92) (1.48) (1.42) (1.95)<br />

S<strong>in</strong>gle parent 3.04 3.00 4.72 3.29 3.13 5.01<br />

(1.55) (1.51) (1.92) (1.52) (1.48) (2.00)<br />

Couple with children 11.41 10.51 12.53 11.16 11.14 12.25<br />

Race<br />

(1.51) (1.38) (1.96) (1.41) (1.37) (1.83)<br />

Non-white -6.34 -6.06 -5.85 -4.95 -5.86 -4.10<br />

Education<br />

(0.76) (0.77) (1.01) (0.88) (0.82) (1.26)<br />

High school to some college 9.86 9.83 8.65 9.12 9.51 7.77<br />

(1.88) (1.86) (2.37) (1.81) (1.83) (1.70)<br />

College or greater 11.79 12.03 10.76 10.35 11.94 8.91<br />

(1.77) (1.73) (2.10) (1.68) (1.70) (1.86)<br />

Income polynomial (4th order) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Wealth polynomial (4th order) Yes Yes<br />

State controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

State premium <strong>in</strong>dex (log po<strong>in</strong>ts) -1.15 -1.47<br />

(0.91) (0.93)<br />

Instrument<br />

Basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

R-squared 0.13 0.27 0.28 0.27 - - - -<br />

N 20,265 20,265 20,265 14,510 20,265 20,265 20,265 14,510<br />

Notes: The dependent variable is the percent of household member-months <strong>in</strong>sured. In the 2SLS specifications, the<br />

basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument is mean log seizable assets for a constant, nationally representative sample of households as though<br />

they lived <strong>in</strong> that state. The excluded demographic groups are age 18-34, s<strong>in</strong>gle, less than high school, <strong>and</strong> white. The<br />

state controls are mean <strong>in</strong>come, percent unemployed, <strong>and</strong> percent covered by Medicaid. See text for a description of the<br />

premium <strong>in</strong>dex. All specifications <strong>in</strong>clude an <strong>in</strong>dicator for the bottom-cod<strong>in</strong>g of seizable assets. Robust st<strong>and</strong>ard errors<br />

clustered at the state level <strong>in</strong> parentheses. Pooled 1999 to 2005 PSID exclud<strong>in</strong>g households with <strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance or a<br />

head age 65 or older. Inflation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 55<br />

Table 1.4: Sensitivity Analysis of the Effect on Coverage<br />

Basel<strong>in</strong>e IV by<br />

Non-homestead<br />

Publicly <strong>in</strong>sured Ins mkt regs Census region Census division group Homestead IV IV Historical IV<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)<br />

ln(w S Dependent variable: Percent of household <strong>in</strong>sured<br />

) 6.30 4.71 5.01 4.23 4.71 4.53 6.16 6.39<br />

(1.11) (1.23) (1.83) (0.72) (1.17) (1.29) (0.67) (0.82)<br />

Demographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

State controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Additional state legislative factors Yes<br />

Census region FE Yes<br />

Census division FE Yes<br />

Instrument<br />

Basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument by group Yes<br />

Homestead <strong>in</strong>strument Yes<br />

Non-homestead <strong>in</strong>strument Yes<br />

Historical <strong>in</strong>strument Yes<br />

N 25,450 20,265 20,265 20,265 20,265 20,265 20,265 17,418<br />

Notes: The dependent variable is the percent of household member-months <strong>in</strong>sured. The basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument is mean log seizable assets for a constant, nationally<br />

representative sample of households as though they lived <strong>in</strong> that state. Means are taken by age <strong>and</strong> education group for the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument by group variable. The<br />

homestead, non-homestead <strong>and</strong> historical homestead <strong>in</strong>struments are constructed similarly to the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument us<strong>in</strong>g seizable home equity, non-homestead seizable<br />

assets, <strong>and</strong> seizable home equity under <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted 1920 homestead exemption laws. Demographic controls are dummies for age group, family structure, race, <strong>and</strong><br />

education. State controls are mean <strong>in</strong>come, percent unemployed, <strong>and</strong> percent covered by Medicaid. Additional state legislative factors are <strong>in</strong>surance market regulations <strong>and</strong><br />

Medicaid Medically Needy program parameters. See text for details. All specifications <strong>in</strong>clude an <strong>in</strong>dicator for the bottom-cod<strong>in</strong>g of seizable assets. Robust st<strong>and</strong>ard errors<br />

clustered at the state level <strong>in</strong> parentheses. Pooled 1999 to 2005 PSID exclud<strong>in</strong>g households with <strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance or a head age 65 or older. Inflation-adjusted to 2005<br />

us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 56<br />

Table 1.5: Heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> the Effect on Coverage<br />

Younger household Older household<br />

Lower <strong>in</strong>come (< Higher <strong>in</strong>come (≥ Lower seizable Higher seizable<br />

head(


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 57<br />

Table 1.6: The Effect on Assets<br />

Dependent variable:<br />

1(homeowner) ln(home equity) 1(homeowner) ln(home equity) 1(vehicle owner) ln(vehicle equity) 1(wealth > 0) ln(wealth)<br />

OLS 2SLS OLS<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)<br />

Homestead <strong>in</strong>strument -0.009 0.000 0.066 0.000<br />

(0.014) (0.000) (0.149) (0.000)<br />

Vehicle <strong>in</strong>strument -0.088 -0.288<br />

(0.064) (0.149)<br />

Basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument 0.008 0.000 -0.078 0.000 -0.025 -0.047 -0.011 -0.011<br />

(0.031) (0.000) (0.178) (0.000) (0.014) (0.041) (0.007) (0.083)<br />

Demographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Income polynomial (4th order) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Wealth polynomial (4th order) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Instrument<br />

Historical homestead Yes Yes<br />

R-squared 0.47 1.00 - - 0.16 0.35 0.10 0.43<br />

N 20,265 17,293 17,418 14,836 20,265 17,699 20,265 17,293<br />

Notes: Regressions of assets (<strong>in</strong>dicators for positive values <strong>and</strong> log values) on state-level measures of asset exemption law (the <strong>in</strong>struments). The homestead <strong>in</strong>strument is mean log seizable<br />

home equity for a constant, nationally representative sample of households as though they lived <strong>in</strong> each state. The historical, vehicle, <strong>and</strong> basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>struments are constructed similarly us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

seizable home equity under <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted 1920 homestead exemption laws, seizable vehicle equity, <strong>and</strong> seizable assets. Demographic controls are dummies for age group, family<br />

structure, race, <strong>and</strong> education. Pooled 1999 to 2005 PSID exclud<strong>in</strong>g households with <strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance or a head age 65 or older. Inflation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U. Homeownership<br />

rate is 72.5 percent. Vehicle ownership rate is 91.0 percent.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 58<br />

Table 1.7: The Effect on Premiums<br />

Dependent variable: ln(premium)<br />

OLS 2SLS<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

Basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument -0.098 -0.098 -0.074 -0.093 -0.111 -0.160<br />

State controls<br />

(0.059) (0.053) (0.038) (0.106) (0.107) (0.076)<br />

Medicaid (share) -0.354 -0.289 -0.417 -0.617<br />

(1.004) (0.794) (1.185) (0.890)<br />

Income 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

Unemployment (share) -0.065 -0.540 1.120 -0.333<br />

Additional state legislative factors<br />

(2.675) (1.850) (3.060) (1.767)<br />

Coverage m<strong>and</strong>ates 0.003 0.000<br />

(0.004) (0.004)<br />

Any will<strong>in</strong>g phamacists 0.058 0.031<br />

(0.051) (0.058)<br />

Any will<strong>in</strong>g provider -0.026 -0.050<br />

(0.060) (0.067)<br />

Community rat<strong>in</strong>g 0.532 -0.016<br />

(0.089) (0.070)<br />

Guarenteed issue -0.450 0.091<br />

(0.133) (0.135)<br />

Charity care pool -0.140 -0.207<br />

(0.060) (0.064)<br />

Plan FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Instrument<br />

Historical <strong>in</strong>strument Yes Yes Yes<br />

R-squared 0.833 0.834 0.865 - - -<br />

N 1,891 1,891 1,891 1,420 1,420 1,420<br />

Notes: The dependent variable is the monthly premium for a 30-year-old non-smok<strong>in</strong>g male<br />

for plans offered by eHealthInsurance. The basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument is mean log seizable assets<br />

for a constant, nationally representative sample of households as though they lived <strong>in</strong> that<br />

state. In the 2SLS specifications, mean seizable home equity under 1920 homestead<br />

exemptions laws is used as an <strong>in</strong>strument. Robust st<strong>and</strong>ard errors clustered at the state<br />

level <strong>in</strong> parentheses. Premiums <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 59<br />

Table 1.8: Basel<strong>in</strong>e Costs Estimates<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

ln(w S Dependent variable: ln(out-of-pocket+1)<br />

OLS 2SLS<br />

) 0.561 0.219 0.271 0.572 0.368 0.350<br />

Age group<br />

(0.014) (0.030) (0.037) (0.014) (0.040) (0.038)<br />

35-44 -0.118 -0.092 -0.237 -0.123<br />

(0.119) (0.120) (0.128) (0.121)<br />

45-54 -0.136 -0.075 -0.255 -0.088<br />

(0.136) (0.133) (0.146) (0.134)<br />

55-64 -0.210 -0.088 -0.368 -0.089<br />

Family structure<br />

(0.155) (0.158) (0.162) (0.158)<br />

Couple 0.226 0.298 0.245 0.335<br />

(0.103) (0.096) (0.107) (0.098)<br />

S<strong>in</strong>gle parent 0.009 0.026 0.083 0.065<br />

(0.121) (0.121) (0.113) (0.119)<br />

Couple with children -0.217 -0.135 -0.138 -0.072<br />

Race<br />

(0.146) (0.141) (0.153) (0.139)<br />

Non-white 0.011 -0.043 -0.049 -0.092<br />

Education<br />

(0.119) (0.122) (0.122) (0.120)<br />

High school to some college 0.205 0.173 -0.001 0.095<br />

(0.113) (0.116) (0.115) (0.115)<br />

College or greater 0.219 0.254 -0.067 0.167<br />

(0.175) (0.176) (0.179) (0.181)<br />

Income polynomial (4th order) Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Wealth polynomial (4th order) Yes Yes<br />

Relative Risk Score polynomial (4th order) Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Instrument<br />

Basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument Yes Yes Yes<br />

R-squared 0.856 0.881 0.882 - - -<br />

N 3,401 3,401 3,401 3,401 3,401 3,401<br />

Notes: Regressions of out-of-pocket payments on seizable assets <strong>in</strong> the sample of un<strong>in</strong>sured households with positive<br />

medical utilization. In the 2SLS specifications, the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument is mean log seizable assets for a constant,<br />

nationally representative sample of households as though they lived <strong>in</strong> state state. The excluded demographic groups are<br />

age 18-34, s<strong>in</strong>gle, less than high school, <strong>and</strong> white. The Relative Risk Score is a measure of utilization based on medical<br />

diagnoses. All specifications <strong>in</strong>clude an <strong>in</strong>dicator for the bottom-cod<strong>in</strong>g of seizable assets. Robust st<strong>and</strong>ard errors<br />

clustered at the state level <strong>in</strong> parentheses. Pooled 2000 to 2005 MEPS <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 60<br />

Table 1.9: Sensitivity Analysis of the Effect on Costs<br />

Nonhomestead<br />

IV Historical IV<br />

High/low<br />

utilization,<br />

basel<strong>in</strong>e IV<br />

High/low<br />

utilization,<br />

historical IV<br />

Hospital Homestead<br />

controls IV<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (5)<br />

ln(w S ) 0.380 0.377 0.382 0.375<br />

(0.066) (0.038) (0.039) (0.039)<br />

ln(w S ) X 1(High utilization) 0.512 0.506<br />

(0.044) (0.046)<br />

ln(w S ) X 1(Low utilization) 0.360 0.372<br />

(0.038) (0.037)<br />

Demographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

State hospital factors<br />

Nonprofit share -0.123<br />

(0.439)<br />

Forprofit share 0.913<br />

(0.694)<br />

DSH payments per 1,000 0.000<br />

(0.000)<br />

Charity care pool <strong>in</strong>dicator 0.009<br />

(0.214)<br />

FQHC per 100,000 0.043<br />

(0.043)<br />

Dependent variable: ln(out-of-pocket+1)<br />

Relative Risk Score polynomial (4th order) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Instrument<br />

Basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument Yes Yes<br />

Homestead <strong>in</strong>strument Yes<br />

Non-homestead <strong>in</strong>strument Yes<br />

Historical <strong>in</strong>strument Yes Yes<br />

N 3,401 3,401 3,401 2,839 3,401 2,839<br />

Notes: Regressions of out-of-pocket payments on seizable assets <strong>in</strong> the sample of un<strong>in</strong>sured households with positive medical<br />

utilization. The basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>strument is mean log seizable assets by state for a constant, nationally representative sample of households<br />

as though they lived <strong>in</strong> each state. The homestead, non-homestead, <strong>and</strong> historical homestead <strong>in</strong>struments are constructed similarly<br />

us<strong>in</strong>g variation <strong>in</strong> seizable home equity, non-homestead seizable assets, <strong>and</strong> seizable home equity under <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted 1920<br />

homestead exemption laws. Demographic controls are dummies for age group, family structure, race, <strong>and</strong> education. The Relative Risk<br />

Score is a measure of utilization based on medical diagnoses. All specifications <strong>in</strong>clude an <strong>in</strong>dicator for the bottom-cod<strong>in</strong>g of seizable<br />

assets. Robust st<strong>and</strong>ard errors clustered at the state level <strong>in</strong> parentheses. Pooled 2000 to 2005 MEPS <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the CPI-U.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 61<br />

Table 1.10: Micro-Simulation Estimates of Percent Covered Without <strong>and</strong> With<br />

Bankruptcy Insurance by Insurance Status<br />

Without bankruptcy<br />

Pr(WTP > premium)<br />

With bankruptcy Difference<br />

Low risk aversion<br />

Un<strong>in</strong>sured 34% 5% 28%<br />

Insured 62% 48% 14%<br />

Difference<br />

Moderate risk aversion<br />

-28% -43% 14%*<br />

Un<strong>in</strong>sured 71% 11% 60%<br />

Insured 85% 62% 23%<br />

Difference<br />

High risk aversion<br />

-14% -51% 37%*<br />

Un<strong>in</strong>sured 91% 21% 70%<br />

Insured 99% 75% 24%<br />

Difference -8% -54% 46%*<br />

Notes: Micro-simulation estimates of the probability that the will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay exceeds the<br />

premium by <strong>in</strong>surance status for a $2,000 deductible plan. Will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay (WTP) calculated<br />

us<strong>in</strong>g CARA utility with parameters of 2.5 x 10^-5 (low risk aversion), 5.0 x 10^-5 (moderate<br />

risk aversion), <strong>and</strong> 7.5 X 10^-5 (high risk aversion). Premiums calculated as the expected<br />

value of medical costs above the deductible scaled up to account for moral hazard (elasticity of<br />

-0.22), adm<strong>in</strong>istrative load<strong>in</strong>g (10 <strong>and</strong> 50 percent), <strong>and</strong> the cross subsidization of unpaid care<br />

(endogenously determ<strong>in</strong>ed). Household-level estimates weighted by the number of <strong>in</strong>dividuals<br />

per household for <strong>in</strong>terpretation at the <strong>in</strong>dividual level.<br />

*Difference-<strong>in</strong>-differences.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 62<br />

Table 1.11: Policy Counterfactuals<br />

Penalty Take-up ! WTP ! Cost ! Surplus<br />

Pigovian penalty<br />

Low risk aversion $218.21 7.5% $10.02 $6.06 $3.95<br />

Moderate risk aversion $218.21 7.3% $11.02 $6.83 $4.19<br />

High risk aversion<br />

PPACA penalty<br />

$218.21 7.9% $12.30 $7.72 $4.58<br />

Low risk aversion $481.43 63.6% -$7.38 $5.34 -$12.72<br />

Moderate risk aversion $481.43 56.4% $3.02 $14.40 -$11.38<br />

High risk aversion<br />

Medical debt non-dischargeable<br />

$481.43 49.7% $11.09 $20.24 -$9.15<br />

Low risk aversion n/a 100.0% -$48.26 -$12.12 -$36.14<br />

Moderate risk aversion n/a 100.0% -$28.18 $12.75 -$40.93<br />

High risk aversion n/a 100.0% -$6.43 $36.74 -$43.17<br />

Notes: Micro-simulation estimates of <strong>in</strong>surance take-up, will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay, costs, <strong>and</strong> social surplus<br />

from different penalty systems relative to a basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> which households can choose bankruptcy at no<br />

cost. The Pigovian penalty is the household-specific social cost of the implicit <strong>in</strong>surance from bankruptcy.<br />

PPACA is the <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted, fully phased-<strong>in</strong> penalty under this legislation, def<strong>in</strong>ed as the greater of<br />

$625 or 2.5 percent of <strong>in</strong>come, up to a maximum of $2,085 per household. Medical debt nondischargeable<br />

exposes households to the full f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk when un<strong>in</strong>sured. Take-up is the percent of<br />

un<strong>in</strong>sured <strong>in</strong>dividuals that take up coverage. Will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay (WTP) is calculated us<strong>in</strong>g CARA utility<br />

with parameters of 2.5 x 10^-5 (low risk aversion), 5.0 x 10^-5 (moderate risk aversion), <strong>and</strong> 7.5 x<br />

10^-5 (high risk aversion). Household-level estimates weighted by number of <strong>in</strong>dividuals per household<br />

for <strong>in</strong>terpretation at the <strong>in</strong>dividual level.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 63<br />

Table 1.12: Summary Statistics: Seizable Assets by Insurance Status<br />

Mean Std. Dev. 5th 25th<br />

Percentile<br />

50th 75th 95th<br />

Panel A: All (n = 22,844)<br />

Seizable assets $216,943 $1,105,939 -$10,148 $2,344 $34,328 $155,219 $796,366<br />

Gross seizable assets $221,434 $1,106,139 $0 $3,500 $38,400 $158,699 $797,593<br />

Seizable home equity (70.4% homeownership) $52,487 $134,239 $0 $0 $0 $53,760 $249,205<br />

Other seizable assets $168,948 $1,054,503 $0 $1,010 $18,000 $81,180 $616,680<br />

Dischargeable debt $6,659 $15,675 $0 $0 $1,024 $7,305 $28,678<br />

Fil<strong>in</strong>g costs<br />

Panel B: Privately Insured (n = 20,197)<br />

$2,000 $0 $2,000 $2,000 $2,000 $2,000 $2,000<br />

Seizable assets $233,241 $1,153,125 -$9,880 $3,423 $42,809 $168,945 $849,475<br />

Gross seizable assets $237,970 $1,153,292 $0 $5,860 $46,294 $172,870 $852,001<br />

Seizable home equity (73.3% homeownership) $56,416 $139,145 $0 $0 $0 $60,320 $260,000<br />

Other seizable assets $181,554 $1,099,952 $0 $2,308 $21,500 $90,649 $654,239<br />

Dischargeable debt $6,898 $15,979 $0 $0 $1,297 $7,684 $29,511<br />

Fil<strong>in</strong>g costs<br />

Panel C: Un<strong>in</strong>sured (n = 2,647)<br />

$2,000 $0 $2,000 $2,000 $2,000 $2,000 $2,000<br />

Seizable assets $41,658 $207,719 -$13,305 $2,000 $2,344 $14,937 $212,000<br />

Gross seizable assets $43,586 $207,884 $0 $0 $637 $16,000 $218,871<br />

Seizable home equity (38.5% homeownership) $10,222 $40,560 $0 $0 $0 $0 $75,000<br />

Other seizable assets $33,364 $197,079 $0 $0 $0 $9,348 $158,089<br />

Dischargeable debt $4,095 $11,615 $0 $0 $0 $3,264 $20,304<br />

Fil<strong>in</strong>g costs $2,000 $0 $2,000 $2,000 $2,000 $2,000 $2,000<br />

Notes: Household-level statistics from the pooled 1999 to 2005 PSID <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U. Excludes households with a head age 65 or<br />

older <strong>and</strong> those with <strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance. See text seizable assets calculation for details.<br />

Table 1.13: Summary Statistics: Medical Costs by Insurance Status<br />

Mean Std. Dev. 5th 25th<br />

Percentile<br />

50th 75th 95th<br />

Panel A: All (n = 34,841)<br />

Charges $6,647 $17,781 $0 $420 $1,836 $6,099 $27,029<br />

Total payments $4,085 $9,704 $0 $309 $1,388 $4,275 $15,859<br />

Private payments $2,974 $8,648 $0 $37 $661 $2,701 $12,448<br />

Public payments $85 $1,094 $0 $0 $0 $0 $78<br />

Misc payments $243 $2,102 $0 $0 $0 $0 $715<br />

Out-of-pocket payments<br />

Panel B: Insured (n = 31,753)<br />

$783 $1,565 $0 $76 $340 $907 $2,934<br />

Charges $7,201 $18,437 $0 $590 $2,201 $6,860 $28,617<br />

Total payments $4,480 $10,131 $0 $455 $1,678 $4,786 $16,767<br />

Private payments $3,391 $9,157 $0 $190 $954 $3,209 $13,528<br />

Public payments $83 $1,078 $0 $0 $0 $0 $89<br />

Misc payments $204 $1,673 $0 $0 $0 $0 $567<br />

Out-of-pocket payments<br />

Panel C: Un<strong>in</strong>sured (n = 3,088)<br />

$801 $1,474 $0 $103 $375 $943 $2,939<br />

Charges $2,691 $11,353 $0 $0 $232 $1,429 $11,022<br />

Total payments $1,267 $4,966 $0 $0 $136 $858 $5,231<br />

Private payments $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0<br />

Public payments $96 $1,200 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0<br />

Misc payments $515 $3,989 $0 $0 $0 $40 $1,678<br />

Out-of-pocket payments $657 $2,097 $0 $0 $80 $543 $2,906<br />

Notes: Household-level statistics from the pooled 2000 to 2005 MEPS <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U. Charges<br />

are the list price of medical care received. Private payments are from private <strong>in</strong>surance providers (e.g., employer sponsored<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance, <strong>in</strong>dividual market <strong>in</strong>surance), <strong>public</strong> payments are from <strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance (e.g, Medicaid), miscellaneous<br />

payments are from other sources (e.g. Workman's Compensation), <strong>and</strong> out-of-pocket payments are from households. Total<br />

payments are the sum of the payment values.


CHAPTER 1. BANKRUPTCY 64<br />

Table 1.14: Summary Statistics: Premiums<br />

N Mean Std. Dev. M<strong>in</strong>. Max.<br />

Premium (per month) 1,891 103 46 30 503<br />

Deductible 1,891 3,351 2,229 0 8,963<br />

Co<strong>in</strong>surance (%) 1,891 15 12 0 50<br />

Notes: Plan characteristics for all plans offered to a 30-year-old non-smok<strong>in</strong>g male <strong>in</strong> each state<br />

on eHealthInsurance. Values <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2005 us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.<br />

Table 1.15: Costs <strong>and</strong> Premiums by Deductible Level<br />

Deductible Pr(Costs > deductible) Calibrated<br />

Premium<br />

Individual Market<br />

$0 46.0% $2,126 $2,140<br />

$1,000 10.4% $1,735 $2,061<br />

$2,000 5.9% $1,546 N/A<br />

$5,000 2.7% $1,259 $874<br />

$10,000 1.5% $1,009 N/A<br />

Notes: Costs are medical costs when un<strong>in</strong>sured. Calibrated premiums are calculated as the<br />

expected value of medical costs above the deductible scaled up to account for moral hazard<br />

(elasticity of -0.22) <strong>and</strong> adm<strong>in</strong>istrative load<strong>in</strong>g (50 percent). Individual market premiums are for<br />

policies start<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> May 2010 issued by Aetna. They are adjusted for <strong>in</strong>flation us<strong>in</strong>g the Medical<br />

Care component of the CPI-U. See Appendix D for details.


Chapter 2<br />

Pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Welfare <strong>in</strong> Health Plan<br />

Choice<br />

with M. Kate Bundorf <strong>and</strong> Jonathan Lev<strong>in</strong><br />

2.1 Introduction<br />

Whether competition <strong>in</strong> health <strong>in</strong>surance markets leads to efficient outcomes is a<br />

central question for health policy. Markets are effective when prices direct consumers<br />

<strong>and</strong> firms to behave efficiently. But <strong>in</strong> health <strong>in</strong>surance markets, prices often do<br />

not reflect the different costs of coverage for different enrollees. This generates two<br />

concerns. If <strong>in</strong>surers receive premiums that do not reflect enrollee risk, they have an<br />

<strong>in</strong>centive to engage <strong>in</strong> risk selection through plan design (??). Similarly, if consumers<br />

face prices that do not reflect cost differences across plans, they may select coverage<br />

<strong>in</strong>efficiently (??). While it is widely recognized that these problems may impair the<br />

efficiency of competitive health <strong>in</strong>surance markets, evidence on their quantitative<br />

importance for social welfare is limited.<br />

In the U.S. private market, employers generally contract with <strong>in</strong>surers to cre-<br />

ate a menu of plans from which employees select coverage. The government or a<br />

quasi-<strong>public</strong> <strong>organization</strong> plays a similar role <strong>in</strong> the U.S. Medicare program <strong>and</strong> the<br />

national systems of Germany <strong>and</strong> the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. To address <strong>in</strong>centive problems <strong>in</strong><br />

65


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 66<br />

plan design, these <strong>in</strong>termediaries have begun to “risk-adjust” payments to plans (?).<br />

Consumer prices, however, are typically not adjusted for <strong>in</strong>dividual risk. Indeed, <strong>in</strong><br />

the U.S., regulations prohibit employers <strong>and</strong> <strong>public</strong> programs from charg<strong>in</strong>g enrollees<br />

different amounts based on nearly all health-related factors. 1 Moreover, even with<strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>stitutional limitations, contributions set by employers or <strong>in</strong> regulated markets may<br />

not be welfare-maximiz<strong>in</strong>g given the complexities of self-selection.<br />

In this paper, we analyze the effect of plan pric<strong>in</strong>g on allocative efficiency. We<br />

beg<strong>in</strong> by mak<strong>in</strong>g a basic theoretical po<strong>in</strong>t regard<strong>in</strong>g plan prices <strong>and</strong> efficient match-<br />

<strong>in</strong>g. Exist<strong>in</strong>g work suggests that, while poorly chosen contribution policies may lead<br />

to <strong>in</strong>efficient outcomes, the problem can be solved by choos<strong>in</strong>g an optimal uniform<br />

contribution (e.g., ????). These analyses, however, make strong assumptions regard-<br />

<strong>in</strong>g the correlation between enrollee risk <strong>and</strong> preferences for coverage. We show that<br />

if these assumptions are violated, no uniform contribution policy leads to efficient<br />

consumer choices.<br />

The ma<strong>in</strong> part of the paper exam<strong>in</strong>es the implications of this observation. We<br />

develop a simple econometric model of health plan dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> costs, estimate the<br />

model on a novel dataset of small employers, <strong>and</strong> then use the parameter estimates to<br />

simulate the welfare implications of alternative pric<strong>in</strong>g policies. Based on our simula-<br />

tions, we estimate that, <strong>in</strong> this sett<strong>in</strong>g, observed pric<strong>in</strong>g policies are less efficient than<br />

what could be achieved with risk-rated plan contributions. The shortfall is between<br />

$60 <strong>and</strong> $325 annually per enrollee, or 2-11% of coverage costs. Employers could<br />

realize approximately 1/4 of this surplus by adjust<strong>in</strong>g their non-risk-rated contribu-<br />

tions, but captur<strong>in</strong>g the rema<strong>in</strong>der would require sett<strong>in</strong>g different prices for people <strong>in</strong><br />

the same firm. We also f<strong>in</strong>d that employees select plans based on private <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

about their health status. A hypothetical social planner who <strong>in</strong>corporated this private<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>to prices could <strong>in</strong>crease welfare by an additional $35-$100 annually per<br />

enrollee. Despite these <strong>in</strong>efficiencies, the observed plan offer<strong>in</strong>gs generate substantial<br />

benefits over any s<strong>in</strong>gle-plan offer<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

An underst<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g of the characteristics of the two <strong>in</strong>surers we study is important<br />

for <strong>in</strong>terpret<strong>in</strong>g these results. One has a fairly broad network of providers <strong>and</strong> relies<br />

1 Premiums vary by smok<strong>in</strong>g status <strong>in</strong> some markets.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 67<br />

on patient cost shar<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> primary care gatekeepers to control utilization. The other<br />

has an <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>and</strong> closed delivery system <strong>and</strong> requires little patient cost shar<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Estimates from the cost model suggest that these <strong>in</strong>surers have very different cost<br />

structures. While costs are similar between the two for <strong>in</strong>dividuals of average health,<br />

the <strong>in</strong>tegrated delivery system has higher costs for healthy enrollees <strong>and</strong> significantly<br />

lower costs for less healthy enrollees.<br />

On the dem<strong>and</strong> side, we f<strong>in</strong>d that household preferences as well as health status<br />

affect plan choice. However, <strong>in</strong> contrast to other studies, we f<strong>in</strong>d that no s<strong>in</strong>gle plan<br />

experiences systematic adverse selection. An <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g feature of our data is that<br />

the plans are not obviously ordered by coverage level: consumers have to trade off<br />

provider network restrictions aga<strong>in</strong>st the level of cost shar<strong>in</strong>g. This “horizontal” plan<br />

differentiation differentiates our sett<strong>in</strong>g from that of many other studies <strong>in</strong> which<br />

consumers choose how much coverage to purchase. We view this horizontal plan<br />

differentiation as the likely explanation for the lack of systematic adverse selection.<br />

This type of differentiation seems particularly salient given the recent evolution<br />

of the health <strong>in</strong>surance market. In 1987, approximately three-quarters of people with<br />

employer-sponsored health <strong>in</strong>surance had conventional coverage, under which plans<br />

differed primarily <strong>in</strong> their cost shar<strong>in</strong>g. By 2007, <strong>in</strong> contrast, the market was domi-<br />

nated by managed care plans which use a mix of supply-side <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>-side utiliza-<br />

tion management (?). This evolution suggests that classic <strong>in</strong>sights based on purely<br />

risk-based sort<strong>in</strong>g may not adequately capture the dynamics of today’s market. 2<br />

The <strong>in</strong>efficiencies we f<strong>in</strong>d are driven by two forces: heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> household<br />

preferences <strong>and</strong> the significant cost advantage of the <strong>in</strong>tegrated system for <strong>in</strong>dividuals<br />

<strong>in</strong> worse health. Our estimates suggest that although high risk households have some<br />

preference for flexibility, a large fraction would choose the <strong>in</strong>tegrated delivery system<br />

if they had to <strong>in</strong>ternalize the relevant cost differential between plans. Achiev<strong>in</strong>g this<br />

with a uniform contribution policy, however, would require that all households face a<br />

steep premium for the more flexible <strong>in</strong>surer. This <strong>in</strong> turn would create a welfare loss<br />

for lower risk households who value flexibility. While the exact numbers we estimate<br />

2 ? stress that a broad view of heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> preferences is important for underst<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g many<br />

aspects of <strong>in</strong>surance markets.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 68<br />

are of course specific to our sett<strong>in</strong>g, the trade-off we identify may be relevant more<br />

broadly. This analysis suggests that the <strong>in</strong>tegrated model of health care delivery faces<br />

an important challenge <strong>in</strong> health <strong>in</strong>surance markets: current pric<strong>in</strong>g policies make it<br />

difficult to target households for whom the <strong>in</strong>tegrated model promises substantial cost<br />

sav<strong>in</strong>gs.<br />

Our analysis ties <strong>in</strong> to past work on health plan choice <strong>and</strong> the efficiency of<br />

health <strong>in</strong>surance markets. We draw on this work on health plan choice, which is<br />

summarized by ? <strong>and</strong> ?, <strong>in</strong> model<strong>in</strong>g how employee dem<strong>and</strong> varies with observed <strong>and</strong><br />

unobserved risk <strong>and</strong> preference characteristics. Our paper is more directly related to<br />

recent work that uses econometric methods to quantify the efficiency implications of<br />

adverse selection <strong>in</strong> health <strong>in</strong>surance markets (?????). Our paper po<strong>in</strong>ts out that<br />

uniform pric<strong>in</strong>g, as is commonly observed, may lead to <strong>in</strong>efficiency when enrollees of<br />

similar risk have different preferences for coverage. These other papers, <strong>in</strong> contrast,<br />

analyze alternative <strong>in</strong>stitutional features of health <strong>in</strong>surance markets that contribute<br />

to adverse selection. We relate both our empirical approach <strong>and</strong> our f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs to these<br />

papers <strong>in</strong> Section 2.5.4.<br />

We emphasize that our analysis has some important limitations. First, it is based<br />

on a particular, <strong>and</strong> only moderately-sized, sample of workers <strong>and</strong> firms. To address<br />

this, we perform a variety of sensitivity analyses on our key parameter estimates,<br />

which we discuss <strong>in</strong> the last section. Second, we take plan offer<strong>in</strong>gs as given. This<br />

seems reasonable given that we are look<strong>in</strong>g at small to medium size employers, but a<br />

broader analysis of pric<strong>in</strong>g ideally would <strong>in</strong>corporate plan design. Third, we do not<br />

address issues of utilization behavior, or try to assess the relative social efficiency of<br />

health care utilization under the different plans <strong>in</strong> our data. F<strong>in</strong>ally, our analysis is<br />

based on a static model, so we abstract from issues of dynamic <strong>in</strong>surance. We discuss<br />

this issue <strong>in</strong> the conclusion.<br />

2.2 Health Plan Pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Market Efficiency<br />

We illustrate the relationship between pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> market efficiency by adapt<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

model of ?. In their model, consumers are dist<strong>in</strong>guished by their forecastable health


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 69<br />

risk, denoted θ. Each consumer chooses between a high-cost plan A <strong>and</strong> a low cost<br />

plan B. We can th<strong>in</strong>k of the plans, for now, as vertically differentiated. The plans’<br />

expected costs of cover<strong>in</strong>g a type-θ consumer are cA(θ) <strong>and</strong> cB(θ). Let ∆c (θ) =<br />

cA(θ) − cB(θ) denote the cost differential. We assume ∆c is strictly positive <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> θ.<br />

Let vA(θ) <strong>and</strong> vB(θ) denote a type θ’s expected (dollar) value from be<strong>in</strong>g covered<br />

by each of the plans. For the moment, the benefits of coverage are determ<strong>in</strong>ed only<br />

by forecastable health risk. We assume that contributions vary across plans but<br />

not across consumers. A consumer who makes a contribution pj to enroll <strong>in</strong> plan<br />

j ∈{A, B} gets a net benefit vj(θ) − pj. 3 Def<strong>in</strong>e ∆v(θ) =vA(θ) − vB(θ) to be the<br />

additional amount a type-θ consumer would pay for the high-cost plan.<br />

The efficient assignment places a type-θ consumer <strong>in</strong> plan A if <strong>and</strong> only if<br />

∆v(θ) − ∆c(θ) ≥ 0.<br />

At the same time, a type-θ consumer will select plan A if <strong>and</strong> only if<br />

∆v(θ) − ∆p ≥ 0,<br />

where ∆p = pA − pB is the <strong>in</strong>cremental contribution for plan A.<br />

Are there prices that lead to an efficient outcome? Assume that ∆v(θ) is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong> θ, which seems appropriate if plan A simply offers more generous coverage or easier<br />

access to care. Then for any <strong>in</strong>cremental contribution ∆p, atype-θ consumer will<br />

choose A if <strong>and</strong> only if θ ≥ θ(∆p), where θ (∆p) is a threshold that can be varied<br />

arbitrarily with ∆p. 4 Therefore it is possible to achieve efficient sort<strong>in</strong>g if <strong>and</strong> only if<br />

the efficient assignment also <strong>in</strong>volves a threshold rule, i.e. if ∆v(θ)−∆c(θ) is negative<br />

up to some θ ∗ <strong>and</strong> positive above it. Intuitively, the requirement for efficiency is that<br />

will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay <strong>in</strong>creases more quickly with risk than the cost differential between<br />

3 Here we make the simplify<strong>in</strong>g assumption, which we ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> our econometric model, that<br />

plan preferences are additively separable <strong>in</strong> the plan premium. See ? for an extensive discussion of<br />

this assumption.<br />

4 An empirical prediction of this model is that plan A will experience unfavorable selection, <strong>and</strong><br />

its risk composition will be worse the larger is ∆p.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 70<br />

plans.<br />

Exist<strong>in</strong>g analyses assume that the surplus function has the requisite s<strong>in</strong>gle cross<strong>in</strong>g<br />

property (e.g., ????). In this case, shown <strong>in</strong> Figure 1:(a), efficiency can be achieved<br />

by sett<strong>in</strong>g ∆p =∆c(θ ∗ ). The problem emphasized <strong>in</strong> the literature is that purchasers<br />

may not choose the correct premium differential. If ∆p is too high, plan A attracts<br />

only very high risks, <strong>and</strong> if prices are based on past outcomes, one can even end<br />

up with an adverse selection “death spiral” (?). Alternatively, if ∆p is too low, too<br />

many people select plan A, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g some for whom the benefits are less than the<br />

<strong>in</strong>cremental social costs.<br />

This familiar analysis can be questioned on several levels. First, even if we cont<strong>in</strong>ue<br />

to assume that consumers differ only <strong>in</strong> their health status <strong>and</strong> plans differ ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong><br />

the amount of coverage they offer, it could be socially efficient for high risks to be <strong>in</strong> a<br />

cost-conscious plan. 5 For <strong>in</strong>stance, the cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs from a plan that actively manages<br />

utilization might more than compensate these consumers for the loss of flexibility. In<br />

this case, shown <strong>in</strong> Figure 1(b), uniform pric<strong>in</strong>g is <strong>in</strong>herently <strong>in</strong>efficient because there<br />

is no way to <strong>in</strong>duce only the relatively high risks to self-select <strong>in</strong>to plan B when<br />

everyone faces the same prices.<br />

Perhaps the more obvious issue from an empirical perspective is that health plans<br />

often differ well beyond offer<strong>in</strong>g “more” or “less” coverage, <strong>and</strong> consumers differ on<br />

dimensions other than health risk. It is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly common for firms to offer em-<br />

ployees an HMO option that places greater restriction on provider choice, <strong>and</strong> a PPO<br />

option that allows broader access to provider, with greater cost shar<strong>in</strong>g. Consumers<br />

<strong>in</strong> relatively poor health may value flexibility but be wary of <strong>in</strong>creased cost-shar<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

As a result, heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> tastes or <strong>in</strong>come may be at least as important as health<br />

status <strong>in</strong> driv<strong>in</strong>g choice.<br />

To capture this, th<strong>in</strong>k of plan A as a PPO <strong>and</strong> plan B as an HMO, <strong>and</strong> suppose<br />

that consumers vary <strong>in</strong> both forecastable risk <strong>and</strong> taste. Specifically, let ε denote a<br />

5 Arguably the benefits of deliver<strong>in</strong>g care efficiently may be largest for the chronically ill. The<br />

most detailed analysis of differences <strong>in</strong> utilization between traditional Medicare coverage <strong>and</strong> Medicare<br />

managed care plans found that the reductions <strong>in</strong> utilization generated by managed care plans<br />

were concentrated among high risk beneficiaries <strong>and</strong> that these reductions <strong>in</strong> utilization were not<br />

associated with differences <strong>in</strong> short term health outcomes (?).


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 72<br />

risk/preference space.<br />

Each of these issues is <strong>in</strong>herently quantitative <strong>in</strong> nature. We use the econometric<br />

model developed <strong>in</strong> the next section to identify the relevant cost <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> param-<br />

eters <strong>and</strong> then evaluate empirically how various pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangements affect social<br />

welfare.<br />

2.3 Data <strong>and</strong> Environment<br />

2.3.1 Institutional Sett<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Our analysis is based on data from a private firm that helps small <strong>and</strong> mid-sized<br />

employers manage health benefits. This firm, who we refer to as the <strong>in</strong>termediary,<br />

obta<strong>in</strong>s agreements from <strong>in</strong>surers to offer plans to small employers, signs up employ-<br />

ers, <strong>and</strong> adm<strong>in</strong>isters their health benefit. We exam<strong>in</strong>e data from 11 employers who<br />

purchased coverage from the <strong>in</strong>termediary <strong>in</strong> a s<strong>in</strong>gle metropolitan area <strong>in</strong> the western<br />

United States dur<strong>in</strong>g 2004 <strong>and</strong> 2005.<br />

In this market, the <strong>in</strong>termediary works with two <strong>in</strong>surers. One <strong>in</strong>surer contracts<br />

non-exclusively with a relatively broad set of providers. It offers an HMO plan (net-<br />

work HMO) that requires enrollees to choose a primary care physician <strong>and</strong> obta<strong>in</strong> a<br />

referral for specialist visits, <strong>and</strong> does not cover care from out-of-network providers.<br />

It also offers a PPO plan (network PPO) that does not require referrals <strong>and</strong> covers<br />

providers outside the plan’s network at an <strong>in</strong>creased cost-share. 7 The second <strong>in</strong>surer<br />

has an <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>and</strong> closed delivery system that facilitates supply side utilization<br />

management. It offers a st<strong>and</strong>ard HMO (<strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO) <strong>and</strong> a po<strong>in</strong>t-of-service op-<br />

tion (<strong>in</strong>tegrated POS) that allows enrollees to seek care outside the <strong>in</strong>tegrated system<br />

at a higher cost.<br />

The employers that hire the <strong>in</strong>termediary beg<strong>in</strong> by choos<strong>in</strong>g which plans to offer<br />

their employees. Employers may customize the basic plans to a limited degree by<br />

7 This <strong>in</strong>surer also offers a po<strong>in</strong>t-of-service (POS) plan that is the HMO with the option to go outof-network<br />

at higher cost. Unfortunately we are not able to dist<strong>in</strong>guish between network POS <strong>and</strong><br />

HMO enrollees. As a result, we simplify our analysis by dropp<strong>in</strong>g the three employer-years where<br />

the network POS was offered. Our results are not sensitive to alternative approaches to h<strong>and</strong>l<strong>in</strong>g<br />

this issue.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 73<br />

vary<strong>in</strong>g characteristics such as the deductible <strong>and</strong> the level of co<strong>in</strong>surance, but most<br />

dimensions are fixed. Employers typically offer four coverage tiers: employee only,<br />

employee plus spouse, employee plus children, <strong>and</strong> employee plus family. 8 The level<br />

of cost shar<strong>in</strong>g varies across coverage tiers. The employers do not offer any health<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance plans beyond those offered by the <strong>in</strong>termediary.<br />

The <strong>in</strong>surers then provide bids for each of the selected plans, rely<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>in</strong>forma-<br />

tion from the <strong>in</strong>termediary. In an employer’s first year with the <strong>in</strong>termediary, this<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation is just the distribution of employees by age <strong>and</strong> sex. In subsequent years,<br />

the <strong>in</strong>surers receive additional <strong>in</strong>formation on the health status of the workers, <strong>in</strong> the<br />

form of a risk score described below. The <strong>in</strong>termediary <strong>in</strong>structs the <strong>in</strong>surers to bid<br />

as if they were cover<strong>in</strong>g all workers with<strong>in</strong> the firm. While the <strong>in</strong>surers provide bids<br />

for each tier, the bids for tiers other than employee-only are simply scaled from the<br />

employee-only bids by a constant that is very similar across employers <strong>and</strong> plans.<br />

After the bids are received, the employer sets the employee contribution for each<br />

plan <strong>and</strong> coverage tier. The employees then make their choices, <strong>and</strong> the plans are<br />

required to accept all employees who choose to enroll. The last step is a series of<br />

payments. For each employee that enrolls <strong>in</strong> a plan, the employer pays the <strong>in</strong>ter-<br />

mediary the <strong>in</strong>surer’s bid. The <strong>in</strong>termediary passes these payments to the <strong>in</strong>surers,<br />

implement<strong>in</strong>g transfers between <strong>in</strong>surers if there is variation <strong>in</strong> the health status of<br />

employees <strong>and</strong> dependents enrolled <strong>in</strong> the different plans.<br />

The <strong>in</strong>termediary uses a st<strong>and</strong>ard methodology for measur<strong>in</strong>g enrollee health sta-<br />

tus, the RxGroup model developed by DxCG, Inc. The model produces risk scores<br />

based on a person’s age, sex, <strong>and</strong> health status, where health status is <strong>in</strong>ferred from<br />

prior use of prescription drugs, reported by the <strong>in</strong>surers. 910 In order to persuade the<br />

8Two firms def<strong>in</strong>e coverage tiers based on employee only, employee plus one dependent, <strong>and</strong><br />

employee plus two or more dependents.<br />

9In our analysis, we use the term “risk score” to refer to the DxCG prediction of an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s<br />

health expenditures relative to the mean of the much larger base sample on which DxCG calibrates<br />

their model. We note that our use of the term risk refers only to the level <strong>and</strong> not to the variance<br />

of the expected expenditure, although we might naturally expect a relationship between the two.<br />

10DxCG uses an <strong>in</strong>ternally-developed algorithm to <strong>in</strong>fer the presence <strong>and</strong> severity of chronic conditions<br />

from prescription drug use. The health expenditure model is estimated on a very large sample<br />

(1,000,000+) of people under 65 with private health <strong>in</strong>surance. Us<strong>in</strong>g the estimated model, the<br />

software predicts covered health expenditures for a given <strong>in</strong>dividual. A score of 1 corresponds to a


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 74<br />

<strong>in</strong>surers to participate, the <strong>in</strong>termediary had to conv<strong>in</strong>ce them they would be ade-<br />

quately compensated for any unfavorable selection they might experience. Because<br />

the risk score is crucial <strong>in</strong> this regard, the <strong>in</strong>termediary worked with the <strong>in</strong>surers to<br />

ensure that the risk scores reflected the underly<strong>in</strong>g health status of enrollees rather<br />

than the methods used by the plans to manage utilization. For <strong>in</strong>stance, one concern<br />

was that the <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>in</strong>surer might substitute low-priced drugs more aggressively,<br />

lead<strong>in</strong>g the algorithm to under-estimate the severity of chronic illness for its enrollees.<br />

Discussions between the <strong>in</strong>termediary <strong>and</strong> the plans along these l<strong>in</strong>es led to a num-<br />

ber of m<strong>in</strong>or adjustments <strong>in</strong> the risk scor<strong>in</strong>g algorithm. Our discussions with the<br />

participants suggest that both the <strong>in</strong>termediary <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>surers had strong <strong>in</strong>cen-<br />

tives to ensure that health status was measured accurately, <strong>and</strong> that it is reasonable<br />

to assume that the risk score accurately captures employee health status <strong>and</strong> is not<br />

contam<strong>in</strong>ated by differences <strong>in</strong> the plans.<br />

In addition to prescription drug utilization, each <strong>in</strong>surer also provides the <strong>in</strong>ter-<br />

mediary with the realized costs for each employer group. The network <strong>in</strong>surer reports<br />

average claims per member per month for enrollees covered by either of the <strong>in</strong>surer’s<br />

products. The <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>in</strong>surer reports similar <strong>in</strong>formation developed from an <strong>in</strong>-<br />

ternal cost account<strong>in</strong>g system. Neither <strong>in</strong>surer dist<strong>in</strong>guishes between its plans when<br />

report<strong>in</strong>g this <strong>in</strong>formation.<br />

2.3.2 Data <strong>and</strong> Descriptive Statistics<br />

Our data <strong>in</strong>cludes all of the <strong>in</strong>formation discussed above: the plan offer<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong><br />

contribution policies of each employer, the risk scores <strong>and</strong> plan choices of employees<br />

<strong>and</strong> their dependents, <strong>and</strong> the bids <strong>and</strong> reported costs of each <strong>in</strong>surer. A primary<br />

strength of the data is that it <strong>in</strong>cludes both dem<strong>and</strong>-side <strong>in</strong>formation on employees<br />

<strong>and</strong> their choice behavior <strong>and</strong> supply-side <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>in</strong>surer costs <strong>and</strong> bids <strong>in</strong> a<br />

sett<strong>in</strong>g with two very different types of <strong>in</strong>surers. In addition, many of the employers<br />

we observe offer nearly identical plans but have different risk profiles <strong>and</strong> contribution<br />

policies which provides useful variation to identify dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> costs.<br />

mean prediction from the orig<strong>in</strong>al estimation sample. See ? for more detail.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 75<br />

Another useful feature of the data is that we observe each employer dur<strong>in</strong>g their<br />

first year of participation <strong>in</strong> the program. Insurers have little <strong>in</strong>formation on firm<br />

characteristics beyond that provided by the <strong>in</strong>termediary dur<strong>in</strong>g the first year, allow-<br />

<strong>in</strong>g us to observe how plans bid when they have similar <strong>in</strong>formation on the likely risk of<br />

a group. 11 On the dem<strong>and</strong> side, a large literature documents that health plan choices<br />

are highly persistent (e.g., ?), so observ<strong>in</strong>g choice behavior <strong>in</strong> the first year likely<br />

provides a good <strong>in</strong>dication of steady-state dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> allows us to observe the plan<br />

characteristics <strong>and</strong> prices at the time of <strong>in</strong>itial choice. The data’s ma<strong>in</strong> limitations are<br />

the fairly small number of observations <strong>and</strong> restricted set of employee characteristics<br />

relative to, say, the HR records of a large employer, <strong>and</strong> also the aggregated report<strong>in</strong>g<br />

of realized costs.<br />

The 11 firms have 2,044 covered employees <strong>and</strong> 4,652 enrollees (employees <strong>and</strong><br />

their dependents). We observe five of the employers for two years, creat<strong>in</strong>g a total of<br />

3,683 employee-years <strong>and</strong> 6,603 enrollee-years. Table 2.1 provides summary statistics<br />

on the covered employees, the enrollees, <strong>and</strong> the firms. Sixty-two percent of employees<br />

are female; the average age is just over forty. Fifty-eight percent of enrollees are female<br />

<strong>and</strong> enrollees are younger on average than employees, driven primarily by covered<br />

children. Twenty-eight percent of employees enroll <strong>in</strong> a plan that covers their spouse<br />

<strong>and</strong> 27 percent enroll <strong>in</strong> a plan that covers at least one child.<br />

Table 2.1 also presents risk scores at the employee, enrollee, <strong>and</strong> employer lev-<br />

els. A score of one represents an average <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong> a nationally representative<br />

sample, <strong>and</strong> a score of two <strong>in</strong>dicates that an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s expected health costs are<br />

twice the average. The average risk scores of employees <strong>and</strong> enrollees are 1.25 <strong>and</strong><br />

1.01, respectively. The difference reflects the lower expected expenditures for covered<br />

children. Average risk ranges widely across employers, from 0.63 to 1.91. One reason<br />

for the degree of variation is the small number of enrollees at some of the firms <strong>in</strong> our<br />

data. This variation plays a key role <strong>in</strong> our analysis. We use <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>in</strong>surer<br />

bids <strong>and</strong> realized costs to estimate models of the relationship between costs <strong>and</strong> risk.<br />

11 In a few cases, an employer had a prior contract with one of the <strong>in</strong>surers. We have exam<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

whether <strong>in</strong>corporat<strong>in</strong>g this <strong>in</strong>to our employee dem<strong>and</strong> model affects our estimates <strong>and</strong> found it did<br />

not. One concern is that this situation could result <strong>in</strong> asymmetric <strong>in</strong>formation between the plans <strong>in</strong><br />

the bidd<strong>in</strong>g, but we th<strong>in</strong>k this is unlikely to be an important problem.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 76<br />

Because <strong>in</strong>surers report both bids <strong>and</strong> costs at the employer level, variation across<br />

employers <strong>in</strong> average risk is necessary to identify these relationships.<br />

Table 2.2 provides <strong>in</strong>formation on the plans offered by the employers <strong>in</strong> our sam-<br />

ple. Most employers offer all four plans, <strong>and</strong> all offer both HMOs <strong>and</strong> at least one<br />

other plan. On average, the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO is the least expensive plan <strong>and</strong> has<br />

the lowest enrollee contribution. This plan features high rates of co<strong>in</strong>surance, a low<br />

deductible, <strong>and</strong> a low out-of-pocket maximum. The network PPO is on average the<br />

most expensive plan <strong>and</strong> has the highest employee contribution. It features lower<br />

co<strong>in</strong>surance rates, higher deductibles <strong>and</strong> higher maximum expenditures. Roughly<br />

speak<strong>in</strong>g, the other two plans fall between these extremes. While bids for each plan<br />

vary substantially across tiers, reflect<strong>in</strong>g differences <strong>in</strong> expected expenditures, the<br />

bids for tiers other than employee only are simply scaled by a factor that is very<br />

similar across both plans <strong>and</strong> employers. Employee contributions also vary across<br />

tiers, with employees typically fac<strong>in</strong>g a greater fraction of the plan bid for dependent<br />

coverage. Variation <strong>in</strong> these contributions is important for the identification of our<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> model. We discuss contributions <strong>in</strong> detail <strong>in</strong> the identification section.<br />

We summarize enrollment patterns <strong>in</strong> Table 2.3. The <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO attracts<br />

by far the most enrollees with a 59% market share among employees <strong>and</strong> 60% market<br />

share among enrollees. We also f<strong>in</strong>d little evidence of extensive risk selection across<br />

the plans. The <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO attracts a slightly younger population, <strong>and</strong> women,<br />

particularly women employees, disproportionately choose the network <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>tegrated<br />

HMOs. But the differences across the plans <strong>in</strong> both average age <strong>and</strong> average risk<br />

score are small. This lack of sort<strong>in</strong>g is not driven by heterogeneity across firms <strong>in</strong> the<br />

choice sets. If we condition on employers that offer both the PPO <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>tegrated<br />

HMO, for example, the average enrollee risk is 1.04 <strong>in</strong> both plans.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 77<br />

2.4 Econometric Model<br />

2.4.1 Consumer Preferences, Plan Costs <strong>and</strong> Market Behav-<br />

ior<br />

In this section, we develop an econometric model that allows us to jo<strong>in</strong>tly estimate<br />

consumer preferences <strong>and</strong> health plan costs. It should be noted that by costs we mean<br />

overall costs to the <strong>in</strong>surer for a given enrollee <strong>in</strong> a given plan. Although we discuss<br />

factors that may expla<strong>in</strong> the variation <strong>in</strong> costs below, overall cost is sufficient for<br />

welfare analysis <strong>and</strong> it is not necessary to decompose whether these cost differences<br />

arise from, for example, moral hazard or physician reimbursement rates or some other<br />

factor (c.f., ?).<br />

In contrast to the simple theoretical model discussed above, the econometric model<br />

allows for multiple plans, vary<strong>in</strong>g plan characteristics, <strong>and</strong> both observable <strong>and</strong> pri-<br />

vately known dimensions of health risk <strong>and</strong> consumer tastes. Nevertheless, we aim<br />

for the most parsimonious model that permits a credible assessment of market ef-<br />

ficiency. In what follows, we describe the key components of the model: consumer<br />

choice, health plan costs, health plan bidd<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong> employer contribution sett<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong><br />

identify the stochastic assumptions on the unobservables that permit estimation.<br />

Consumer Choice<br />

We use a st<strong>and</strong>ard latent utility model to describe household choice behavior,<br />

where a household’s (money-metric) utility from choos<strong>in</strong>g a plan depends on a com-<br />

b<strong>in</strong>ation of household <strong>and</strong> plan characteristics. Specifically, household h’s utility from<br />

choos<strong>in</strong>g plan j is:<br />

uhj = φjαφ + xhαxj + ψ(rh + µh; αrj) − pj + σεεhj. (2.1)<br />

In this representation, household utility depends on observable plan characteris-<br />

tics φj, the monthly plan contribution pj, 12 observable household demographics xh,<br />

12 We convert employee contributions, which are made with pre-tax dollars, to post-tax dollars by<br />

adjust<strong>in</strong>g them by the marg<strong>in</strong>al tax rate (see Footnote 13 for discussion). For a given household


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 78<br />

an idiosyncratic preference εhj, <strong>and</strong> household health risk. Our measure of household<br />

health risk is aggregated from the <strong>in</strong>dividual level. For each <strong>in</strong>dividual i, we decom-<br />

pose health risk <strong>in</strong>to the observable risk score ri <strong>and</strong> additional privately known health<br />

factors µi. The µis capture <strong>in</strong>formation about health status that may affect choice<br />

behavior, but is not subject to risk adjustment. Equivalently, we can <strong>in</strong>terpret µi as<br />

measurement error <strong>in</strong> the risk score. We assume that each µi is an i.i.d. draw from a<br />

normal distribution with mean zero <strong>and</strong> variance σ 2 µ, <strong>and</strong> that the idiosyncratic tastes<br />

εhj are i.i.d. type I extreme value r<strong>and</strong>om variables (i.e. logit errors).<br />

We h<strong>and</strong>le heterogeneity <strong>in</strong> household size <strong>and</strong> composition by assum<strong>in</strong>g that,<br />

apart from the treatment of health risk, each household behaves as if it had a rep-<br />

resentative member with characteristics equal to the average of those of household<br />

members. 13 We parameterize household risk us<strong>in</strong>g two variables: the average risk<br />

of household members (i.e. the average of the ri + µi) <strong>and</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dicator of whether<br />

the household <strong>in</strong>cludes a high risk member. We def<strong>in</strong>e high risk as be<strong>in</strong>g above 2.25,<br />

which corresponds to the 90% percentile of the observed risk score distribution. The<br />

other household characteristics <strong>in</strong> the model are the averages of age <strong>and</strong> the male<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicator among covered household members as well as imputed household <strong>in</strong>come. 14<br />

In addition to the employee contribution, plan characteristics φj <strong>in</strong>clude a dummy<br />

variable for plan (the network HMO <strong>and</strong> PPO <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO <strong>and</strong> POS),<br />

the relevant co<strong>in</strong>surance rate <strong>and</strong> deductible for the given employee, <strong>and</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dicator<br />

of non-st<strong>and</strong>ard drug coverage. 15 To be consistent with our approach to household<br />

h, letρh be the nom<strong>in</strong>al contribution <strong>and</strong> τh the household’s marg<strong>in</strong>al tax rate. The tax adjusted<br />

contribution is ph =(1− τh)ρh.<br />

13 We experimented with estimat<strong>in</strong>g different weights for household members, <strong>and</strong> also with restrict<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the sample to <strong>in</strong>dividual enrollees. Neither has much effect on our results. The Appendix<br />

<strong>in</strong>cludes <strong>in</strong>dividual enrollee estimates.<br />

14 We impute taxable <strong>in</strong>come for each household <strong>in</strong> our sample by estimat<strong>in</strong>g a model of household<br />

<strong>in</strong>come as a function of worker age, sex, family structure, firm size <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry us<strong>in</strong>g data from the<br />

Current Population Survey for 2004 <strong>and</strong> 2005 on workers with employer-sponsored health <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

<strong>in</strong> the correspond<strong>in</strong>g state. We then use the model to impute household <strong>in</strong>come for each employee <strong>in</strong><br />

our data <strong>in</strong>corporat<strong>in</strong>g r<strong>and</strong>om draws from the posterior distributions of the regression coefficients<br />

<strong>and</strong> the st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of the residuals. Based on these predictions, we use Taxsim to calculate<br />

marg<strong>in</strong>al tax rates based on federal, state, <strong>and</strong> FICA taxes mak<strong>in</strong>g some assumptions on the correlation<br />

of coverage tier with fil<strong>in</strong>g status <strong>and</strong> number of dependents. The average taxable family<br />

<strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al tax rate for workers <strong>in</strong> our sample are about $73,00 <strong>and</strong> 41%, respectively.<br />

15 While the prescription drug coverage for each plan is complicated, comprised of both formulate


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 81<br />

where rf denotes the average risk of employees <strong>in</strong> firm f, which the <strong>in</strong>surer forecasts<br />

us<strong>in</strong>g the available demographic <strong>in</strong>formation, xf. 16<br />

We model expected plan bids as a mark-up over expected cost. So plan j’s bid<br />

for firm f is:<br />

Bjf = δj · (aj + bj · (E[rf|xf] − 1)) + νjf, (2.7)<br />

where νjf is an <strong>in</strong>dependent mean zero r<strong>and</strong>om variable. The new parameter <strong>in</strong>tro-<br />

duced <strong>in</strong> the bid model is the mark-up, δj. We constra<strong>in</strong> the mark-up to be constant<br />

across the plans offered by a particular <strong>in</strong>surer. Although <strong>in</strong> theory an <strong>in</strong>surer could<br />

vary the mark-up across its different plans, because the cost data are at the <strong>in</strong>surer-<br />

firm level, we are unable to identify separately the mark-up <strong>and</strong> the fixed costs for<br />

each plan offered by an <strong>in</strong>surer. Naturally we expect the mark-up parameters to be<br />

larger than one.<br />

Employer Contribution Sett<strong>in</strong>g<br />

The last part of our model specifies how employers set required plan contributions.<br />

We adopt a simple model <strong>in</strong> which employers pass on a fraction of their cost for the<br />

lowest cost plan, <strong>and</strong> then a fraction of the <strong>in</strong>cremental cost for higher cost plans. We<br />

allow these fractions, denoted β <strong>and</strong> γ, to vary across firm-years <strong>and</strong> coverage tiers.<br />

Let B lf denote the m<strong>in</strong>imum bid received for coverage tier l <strong>in</strong> firm-year f, de-<br />

note plan j’s bid for coverage tier l <strong>in</strong> firm-year f as Bjlf. We model the required<br />

contribution as:<br />

pjlf = βlf · B lf + γlf · (Bjlf − B lf)+ξjlf. (2.8)<br />

This model describes employer behavior <strong>in</strong> our data remarkably well. The resid-<br />

uals from the l<strong>in</strong>ear regression (2.8) have a st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of 7.64, <strong>and</strong> the R-<br />

squared is 0.99. As noted above, approximately half of the firms <strong>in</strong> our data choose<br />

a ”proportional pass-through” strategy where β = γ. The others choose an ”<strong>in</strong>cre-<br />

mental pass-through” strategy <strong>in</strong> which β


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 82<br />

2.4.2 Discussion of Model <strong>and</strong> Identification<br />

The key quantities <strong>in</strong> our model are plan costs <strong>and</strong> plan dem<strong>and</strong> as functions of fore-<br />

castable risk, <strong>and</strong> the price elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong>. The former determ<strong>in</strong>e the efficient<br />

allocation of households to plans, while the latter determ<strong>in</strong>es how price changes affect<br />

self-selection. We now discuss the variation <strong>in</strong> the data that identifies each of these<br />

quantities <strong>in</strong> estimation.<br />

Identify<strong>in</strong>g plan costs is straightforward. The effect of forecastable risk on plan<br />

costs is identified by variation across firms <strong>in</strong> the average risk scores of workers <strong>and</strong><br />

dependents, <strong>and</strong> how it affects <strong>in</strong>surer bids <strong>and</strong> realized costs. We identify the mark-<br />

up parameters, δj, by the difference between the plan bids <strong>and</strong> reported costs. A<br />

ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed assumption <strong>in</strong> estimat<strong>in</strong>g mark-ups is that <strong>in</strong>surers base their bids on<br />

only the <strong>in</strong>formation about employees that is provided by the <strong>in</strong>termediary. We<br />

discuss this assumption more below, but we believe it is reasonable given the small<br />

size of the contracts <strong>and</strong> the fact that we consider only the first year of plan bids.<br />

The effect of household risk on choice behavior (i.e. the coefficients αrj <strong>in</strong> the<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> equation) is identified by variation <strong>in</strong> observable risk across households. Our<br />

model also allows private <strong>in</strong>formation about health status to affect choice. The key<br />

parameter here is the variance of the private <strong>in</strong>formation, σ 2 µ, which is identified by<br />

the correlation between consumers’ enrollment decisions <strong>and</strong> plans’ realized costs.<br />

This identification is aided by cross-firm variation <strong>in</strong> contribution policies <strong>and</strong> demo-<br />

graphics that, conditional on observable health risk, affect enrollment but not realized<br />

costs. 17 The identification obta<strong>in</strong>ed from price variation is similar to the identifica-<br />

tion <strong>in</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard selection models, <strong>and</strong> relies on the exclusion restriction if a given<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividual i is enrolled <strong>in</strong> a given plan j, his or her utilization does not depend on<br />

the per-month premium (although of course it may depend on other elements of the<br />

plan such as the copayment rate).<br />

The most subtle identification issues arise <strong>in</strong> estimat<strong>in</strong>g the effect of plan con-<br />

tributions on dem<strong>and</strong>. Plan contributions are the result of plan bids <strong>and</strong> employer<br />

pass-through decisions. Our model allows four sources of variation <strong>in</strong> contributions:<br />

17 Our dem<strong>and</strong> model also <strong>in</strong>cludes plan characteristics such as co<strong>in</strong>surance <strong>and</strong> deductible. Their<br />

coefficients are identified off cross-firm <strong>and</strong> cross-tier variation <strong>in</strong> the characteristics.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 83<br />

cross-firm variation <strong>in</strong> demographics (xf) that leads plans to submit different bids,<br />

idiosyncratic variation <strong>in</strong> plan bids (νjf), cross-firm <strong>and</strong> cross-tier variation <strong>in</strong> em-<br />

ployer pass-through rates (γjlf), <strong>and</strong> idiosyncratic variation <strong>in</strong> the plan contributions<br />

(ξjlf). 18<br />

Figure 2.4 demonstrates this variation by plott<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>cremental contributions<br />

aga<strong>in</strong>st the <strong>in</strong>cremental bids for each plan relative to the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO, which is<br />

usually the plan requir<strong>in</strong>g the lowest employee contribution. We plot contribution<br />

rates for two tiers, employee only <strong>and</strong> employee plus spouse, to demonstrate how<br />

contributions vary across tier. For the employee plus spouse data, we divide both<br />

the contributions <strong>and</strong> the bids by two to obta<strong>in</strong> per-enrollee prices. Difference <strong>in</strong><br />

the bids for the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO <strong>and</strong> the network PPO ranges from $50 to $150<br />

per month, with a large fraction due to cross-firm variation <strong>in</strong> demographic risk.<br />

Comb<strong>in</strong>ations of <strong>in</strong>cremental contributions <strong>and</strong> bids that lie along the 45 degree l<strong>in</strong>e<br />

<strong>in</strong> Figure 2.3 represent employers who pass on the full marg<strong>in</strong>al cost of higher plan<br />

bids to employees. A subset of employers adopt this approach. Another subset of<br />

employers fully subsidize the higher cost plans, sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>cremental contributions of<br />

zero. Between these two extremes are employers who partially subsidize higher cost<br />

plans through contribution policies. In general, employers tend to pass on a greater<br />

portion of <strong>in</strong>cremental costs for plans with dependent coverage.<br />

The availability of multiple sources of variation permits some flexibility <strong>in</strong> estimat-<br />

<strong>in</strong>g price elasticities. Recall that accurate identification requires us<strong>in</strong>g price variation<br />

that is not correlated with idiosyncratic household tastes εhj or privately known health<br />

risk µh. Our basel<strong>in</strong>e estimates use all four sources of variation. We also employ <strong>in</strong>-<br />

strumental variables to isolate different sources of variation. The <strong>in</strong>struments are<br />

predicted plan contributions based on alternative covariates. The bottom l<strong>in</strong>e from<br />

these specifications is that our price elasticity estimates are quite robust to focus<strong>in</strong>g<br />

on different sources of variation <strong>in</strong> contributions. This robustness, despite our rela-<br />

tively small sample, suggests that endogeneity may not be an important concern, at<br />

least <strong>in</strong> this sett<strong>in</strong>g. Nevertheless, we now discuss the issues <strong>in</strong> detail.<br />

18 We also <strong>in</strong>troduce variation <strong>in</strong> employee contributions through the imputed marg<strong>in</strong>al tax rates,<br />

but we control for imputed <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> relevant household demographics <strong>in</strong> the dem<strong>and</strong> equation.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 84<br />

Perhaps the most obvious identification concern is that employers believe their<br />

employees will prefer a particular plan <strong>and</strong> price accord<strong>in</strong>gly. This could mean cater-<br />

<strong>in</strong>g to employees with a low contribution, or sett<strong>in</strong>g a high contribution to pass on<br />

costs. Either would generate a correlation between the idiosyncratic part of the con-<br />

tribution ξjlf <strong>and</strong> household preferences εhj. To mitigate this concern, we <strong>in</strong>strument<br />

for the actual plan contribution us<strong>in</strong>g the predicted value (ˆpjlf) from the contribution<br />

model (2.8). We take this as our preferred specification <strong>in</strong> perform<strong>in</strong>g welfare analysis<br />

although the results are similar to the basel<strong>in</strong>e case with no <strong>in</strong>struments.<br />

A second concern is that plan bids are correlated with unobserved household<br />

tastes. This could happen if an <strong>in</strong>surer believed its plan was attractive due to, say,<br />

a nearby cl<strong>in</strong>ic location. It would generate a correlation between the idiosyncratic<br />

bid component, νjf, <strong>and</strong> household preferences εhj. We view this problem as most<br />

likely of marg<strong>in</strong>al importance given the limited <strong>in</strong>formation on the part of <strong>in</strong>surers.<br />

Nevertheless, we check our estimates by <strong>in</strong>strument<strong>in</strong>g for plan contribution with a<br />

predicted value that is constructed by plugg<strong>in</strong>g the predicted bid ˆ Bjf from (2.7) <strong>in</strong>to<br />

the contribution model (2.8). This specification purges the variation <strong>in</strong> both νjf <strong>and</strong><br />

ξjlf. The results are similar to our preferred specification.<br />

A third issue for identification is that employer pass-through rates might be sys-<br />

tematically <strong>in</strong>fluenced by employee preferences. This also seems unlikely, ma<strong>in</strong>ly<br />

because pass-through rates <strong>in</strong> our data are uncorrelated with observable differences<br />

across firms. Figure 2.4 plots employer pass-through rates aga<strong>in</strong>st employee health<br />

status, dependent health status, worker <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> firm size. There is no correla-<br />

tion, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that cross-firm differences <strong>in</strong> contribution policies may be due more<br />

to idiosyncratic factors, such as management philosophy, than employee tastes. Nev-<br />

ertheless, we aga<strong>in</strong> use an IV strategy to verify that our results are not driven by a<br />

correlation between the pass-through coefficients γjlf <strong>and</strong> unobserved preferences εhj.<br />

To this end, we <strong>in</strong>strument for plan contribution us<strong>in</strong>g predicted values from a variant<br />

of the contribution model (2.8) <strong>in</strong> which pass-through coefficients are restricted to be<br />

identical across firms. This purges cross-firm variation <strong>in</strong> γjlf as well as the variation<br />

<strong>in</strong> ξjlf. The results are aga<strong>in</strong> similar although with large st<strong>and</strong>ard errors. 19<br />

19 A f<strong>in</strong>al identification concern is that household choices may be <strong>in</strong>fluenced by the health status of


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 88<br />

2.5.1 Model Estimates<br />

Table 2.4 presents parameter estimates from three different specifications of the de-<br />

m<strong>and</strong> model. 21 The first column is a basel<strong>in</strong>e model where we do not <strong>in</strong>strument<br />

for plan contributions, <strong>and</strong> do not allow for private <strong>in</strong>formation about household<br />

risk. The second <strong>and</strong> third columns <strong>in</strong>strument for plan contributions us<strong>in</strong>g the pre-<br />

dicted values from the contribution model (2.8). The third column, which is our<br />

preferred specification, allows for private <strong>in</strong>formation about risk. To scale the utility<br />

to money-metric form, we divide each coefficient by the coefficient on the monthly<br />

contribution <strong>and</strong> adjust the st<strong>and</strong>ard errors accord<strong>in</strong>gly. We report the price effects<br />

as semi-elasticities at the bottom of the table.<br />

Effect of Demographics <strong>and</strong> Risk on Choice<br />

The dem<strong>and</strong> estimates <strong>in</strong>dicate that overall sort<strong>in</strong>g on the basis of risk is rather<br />

modest, but that different plans experience unfavorable selection across differ<strong>in</strong>g com-<br />

ponents risk. Older employees, who on average cost more to <strong>in</strong>sure, prefer the network<br />

HMO <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>tegrated POS plan to the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO. An additional year of age<br />

is associated with an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay for the network HMO relative<br />

to the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO of $1.75 per month (Column 1). Because older people are<br />

often <strong>in</strong> worse health, they are likely to place a higher value on the broader provider<br />

network of the network plan which would give them greater freedom <strong>in</strong> choos<strong>in</strong>g<br />

among providers. Women, who at the age of workers <strong>in</strong> our data typically cost more<br />

to <strong>in</strong>sure than men, prefer the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO to either the <strong>in</strong>tegrated POS plan<br />

or the network PPO. Women are will<strong>in</strong>g to pay $35 per month less than men for<br />

the network PPO relative to the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO (Column 1). Women may have<br />

stronger preferences for the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO if they perceive that it is more effective<br />

<strong>in</strong> provid<strong>in</strong>g preventive cares s<strong>in</strong>ce, <strong>in</strong> this age group, more preventive services are<br />

recommended for women than for men. The effects of age <strong>and</strong> sex are not particularly<br />

sensitive to the use of <strong>in</strong>struments for the employee contribution (Column 2) or the<br />

21 The Table does not report every parameter. The parameters not reported are the plan fixed<br />

effects, <strong>and</strong> the coefficients on imputed household <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dicator for non-st<strong>and</strong>ard drug<br />

coverage.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 89<br />

<strong>in</strong>corporation of unobserved risk (Column 3).<br />

We f<strong>in</strong>d some sort<strong>in</strong>g on the basis of health status conditional on age <strong>and</strong> sex,<br />

driven primarily by hav<strong>in</strong>g a very high risk household member. The effects of the<br />

l<strong>in</strong>ear risk score on plan choice are generally small <strong>and</strong> imprecise. Households with<br />

a high risk member, however, are less likely to enroll <strong>in</strong> the network HMO <strong>and</strong> more<br />

likely to enroll <strong>in</strong> the network PPO than the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO. In our preferred spec-<br />

ification (Column 3), an employee with a high risk family member is will<strong>in</strong>g to pay<br />

$28 per month more than an employee without a high risk family member to enroll<br />

<strong>in</strong> the network PPO relative to the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO. This is consistent, once aga<strong>in</strong>,<br />

with those who are more likely to use care plac<strong>in</strong>g a greater value on less restrictive<br />

provider networks.<br />

Our results also suggest that private <strong>in</strong>formation about health risk plays a role<br />

<strong>in</strong> plan choice, although the estimate is not precise. We estimate that the st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

deviation of private risk <strong>in</strong>formation σµ is 0.68, which is substantial relative to the<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation of the observed risk scores (1.56 <strong>in</strong> Table 2.1). Roughly speak<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

observed risk scores appear to pick up just over 2/3 of the health status <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

that factors <strong>in</strong>to plan choice.<br />

While our f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs with respect to risk selection are not <strong>in</strong>consistent with exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

research, they suggest a relatively complex pattern of sort<strong>in</strong>g. Much of the exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

literature f<strong>in</strong>ds evidence of unfavorable selection <strong>in</strong>to more generous plans (??) .<br />

We also f<strong>in</strong>d that the highest risk enrollees favor the most flexible plan, the network<br />

PPO. Overall, however, the average risk across plans is quite similar due to off-<br />

sett<strong>in</strong>g selection along different demographic dimensions, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g age <strong>and</strong> gender,<br />

that are correlated with risk. This f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g is consistent with the idea that the plans<br />

cater to <strong>in</strong>dividuals with different tastes for health care, rather than offer<strong>in</strong>g different<br />

quantities of care, or target<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividuals of different health status.<br />

Effect of Plan Prices on Choice<br />

In the bottom panel, we present price semi-elasticities of dem<strong>and</strong>, def<strong>in</strong>ed as the<br />

percentage decrease <strong>in</strong> market share result<strong>in</strong>g from a $100 <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the annual<br />

enrollee contribution, evaluated at the mean choice probability for each plan. On


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 90<br />

average, a $100 dollar <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the annual enrollee contribution decreases market<br />

share by 7 to 9 percent. While <strong>in</strong>strument<strong>in</strong>g for the contribution reduces the precision<br />

of the estimate, it has relatively little effect on its magnitude. These estimates suggest<br />

that dem<strong>and</strong> is relatively <strong>in</strong>elastic, <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with other estimates <strong>in</strong> the literature. In<br />

the Onl<strong>in</strong>e Appendix, we discuss studies <strong>in</strong> sett<strong>in</strong>gs similar to ours. Across these<br />

studies, a $100 <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the annual contribution reduces market share by 1.6 to 9.6<br />

percent, plac<strong>in</strong>g our estimate <strong>in</strong> the middle to high end of the range.<br />

The results <strong>in</strong> Table 2.4 also <strong>in</strong>clude the estimated value of plan characteristics<br />

other than price, such as co<strong>in</strong>surance rate <strong>and</strong> deductible. Enrollees appear to be<br />

moderately sensitive to both. We estimate that a 10 percentage po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong><br />

the co<strong>in</strong>surance rate is valued at approximately $276 dollars annually, which is about<br />

10 percent of the annual cost per enrollee reported by the <strong>in</strong>surers. Our estimates<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicate that enrollees are not particularly sensitive to the deductible when choos<strong>in</strong>g<br />

among plans. 22<br />

Because the estimates of risk <strong>and</strong> price elasticity are the key parameters for our<br />

welfare calculations, we have exam<strong>in</strong>ed the sensitivity of these estimates to a variety<br />

of issues. In the Onl<strong>in</strong>e Appendix we present estimates where we vary the sample of<br />

households <strong>and</strong> use different <strong>in</strong>struments (discussed <strong>in</strong> Section 2.5.4) for the employee<br />

contributions. We also discuss specifications with alternative sets of controls. The<br />

bottom l<strong>in</strong>e is that the estimates are robust to variation across these dimensions.<br />

Structure of Plan Costs<br />

The difference <strong>in</strong> cost structures for the <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>and</strong> network <strong>in</strong>surer can be<br />

seen <strong>in</strong> the raw data depicted <strong>in</strong> Figures 2.5 <strong>and</strong> 2.6. Figure 2.5 is a scatterplot of<br />

enrollee risk scores aga<strong>in</strong>st realized costs. Each po<strong>in</strong>t corresponds to an <strong>in</strong>surer-firm-<br />

year. The x-axis is the average risk of the <strong>in</strong>surer’s enrollees; the y-axis is the reported<br />

costs per enrollee. The l<strong>in</strong>es represent the model’s prediction (shown <strong>in</strong> Table 2.5)<br />

of expected costs for the network PPO <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO. Figure 2.6 displays<br />

correspond<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation for bids. It shows the average risk of a firm’s employees<br />

plotted aga<strong>in</strong>st plan bids, with each observation at the plan-firm-year level.<br />

22 The results are unchanged when out-of-pocket maximum are <strong>in</strong>cluded as plan characteristics.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 91<br />

As the figures illustrate, the plans seem to have similar costs for enrollees with<br />

average health risk <strong>and</strong> divergent costs for enrollees <strong>in</strong> good <strong>and</strong> poor health. The<br />

expected monthly cost for an enrollee with a risk score of 1 is $235 for the <strong>in</strong>tegrated<br />

HMO, $236 for the <strong>in</strong>tegrated POS, $218 for the network HMO, <strong>and</strong> $238 for the<br />

network PPO. For less healthy enrollees, the <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>in</strong>surer has a substantial cost<br />

advantage. The expected monthly cost of an enrollee with a risk score of two is $309<br />

for the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO, compared to $507 for the network HMO <strong>and</strong> $413 for the<br />

network PPO. Network plans do relatively well for low risks. The expected monthly<br />

cost for an enrollee with a risk score of 0.5 is $198 for the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO, as opposed<br />

to $151 for the network PPO <strong>and</strong> $74 for the network HMO.<br />

The structure of plan costs we estimate is consistent with the basic idea that<br />

patient cost shar<strong>in</strong>g may be effective at limit<strong>in</strong>g provider visits while supply-side<br />

mechanisms may be more effective at limit<strong>in</strong>g costs conditional on receiv<strong>in</strong>g services<br />

(see, e.g., ?). While we do not have visit-level data to support the claim, the steep cost<br />

curves for the network plans are consistent with cost shar<strong>in</strong>g limit<strong>in</strong>g visits, particu-<br />

larly for low risks, but hav<strong>in</strong>g little effect on the high risks who consume healthcare<br />

on the <strong>in</strong>tensive marg<strong>in</strong>. In contrast, the <strong>in</strong>tegrated plans with their relatively low<br />

cost shar<strong>in</strong>g but stronger supply side utilization controls may be less effective at lim-<br />

it<strong>in</strong>g provider visits for low risks but more effective at manag<strong>in</strong>g costs conditional on<br />

provider visits for the high risks. Another factor expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the relatively high costs<br />

for low risks <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>tegrated plan may be the greater use of preventive services.<br />

These results also provide some <strong>in</strong>sight on the potential issue of bias <strong>in</strong> the risk<br />

scores. As discussed earlier, if the risk scores are biased, the likely direction of the bias<br />

is an underestimate of the risk of the enrollees <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>tegrated plan. This is because<br />

the risk scores are based on the types of prescription drugs used by plan enrollees<br />

<strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>tegrated plan more aggressively manages drug utilization. If this were the<br />

case, then we would underestimate the cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs for high risks generated by the<br />

<strong>in</strong>tegrated plan. In other words, the large cost differentials we observe would be even<br />

larger. While we believe that bias <strong>in</strong> the risk scores is unlikely to be an important<br />

issue, if it exists, it would likely re<strong>in</strong>force our key f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs.<br />

We note that our estimates for the <strong>in</strong>tegrated POS plan <strong>in</strong>dicate that its costs


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 92<br />

are more similar to those of the network plans than the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO. While<br />

these results are not consistent with our f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs regard<strong>in</strong>g the differences <strong>in</strong> the cost<br />

structures between the two types of <strong>in</strong>surers, s<strong>in</strong>ce the bulk of the <strong>in</strong>tegrated plans<br />

enrollment is concentrated <strong>in</strong> the HMO product, it is likely that the HMO is more<br />

representative of its cost structure, particularly given our small sample size. The<br />

other <strong>in</strong>consistency <strong>in</strong> our cost results is the difference <strong>in</strong> the cost structure between<br />

the plans offered by the network <strong>in</strong>surer. In particular, <strong>in</strong> contrast to the <strong>in</strong>tegrated<br />

HMO, the network HMO appears not to generate cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs for high risks relative<br />

to the PPO product. While it is difficult to underst<strong>and</strong> why this plan would be<br />

more expensive for unhealthy enrollees relative to its less managed PPO counterpart,<br />

we note that our estimates are based on relatively small samples, mak<strong>in</strong>g it not<br />

particularly surpris<strong>in</strong>g that some of our results may not have an <strong>in</strong>tuitive explanation.<br />

In addition, many factors are likely to affect health plans costs so our estimates may<br />

also reflect true differences <strong>in</strong> cost structures for which we did not have strong prior<br />

beliefs. The estimated mark-up varies across <strong>in</strong>surers. We estimate that the network<br />

<strong>in</strong>surer <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>in</strong>surer bid 24 percent <strong>and</strong> 8 percent over expected costs,<br />

respectively.<br />

The sensitivity of cost differentials as a function of enrollee risk, compared to the<br />

relatively modest effect of risk on plan preferences, has an important implication.<br />

It <strong>in</strong>dicates that as consumer risk varies, changes <strong>in</strong> relative plan costs rather than<br />

changes <strong>in</strong> preferences will drive the efficient allocation. As our simple theory model<br />

illustrated, this will not happen under self-selection without a mechanism that allows<br />

different risk groups to face different premium differentials. In our sett<strong>in</strong>g, prices do<br />

not have this feature, suggest<strong>in</strong>g the potential for <strong>in</strong>efficiency. We return to this po<strong>in</strong>t<br />

<strong>in</strong> the next section, when we quantify social welfare.<br />

A factor to keep <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d when evaluat<strong>in</strong>g our estimates of plan costs is that we<br />

observe the <strong>in</strong>surers’ costs of coverage, not the overall dollars spent on care. The<br />

dist<strong>in</strong>ction is important because, <strong>in</strong> plans with copayments <strong>and</strong> deductibles, enrollees<br />

bear a share of the cost of care that we do not capture <strong>in</strong> our data. These payments<br />

are largest at the network PPO <strong>and</strong> smallest at the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO. While our<br />

model assumes that these payments will be <strong>in</strong>ternalized <strong>in</strong> mak<strong>in</strong>g plan choices, they


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 93<br />

do affect the <strong>in</strong>terpretation of the effects of the different plan types on utilization of<br />

care. In particular,the reduction <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>sured costs for low risks <strong>in</strong> the network plan may<br />

represent, at least <strong>in</strong> part, a shift from <strong>in</strong>sured to un<strong>in</strong>sured payments, rather than a<br />

reduction <strong>in</strong> utilization or prices. For high risks, <strong>in</strong> contrast, the difference <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>sured<br />

costs between the plans likely underestimates the extent to which the <strong>in</strong>tegrated plan<br />

reduces total costs.<br />

2.5.2 Quantify<strong>in</strong>g Social Welfare Inefficiencies<br />

In this section, we use the estimated dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> cost model to compute the <strong>in</strong>effi-<br />

ciency associated with observed contribution policies relative to alternative efficient<br />

benchmarks. We also compare welfare between the observed policies <strong>and</strong> alterna-<br />

tive uniform contribution policies to demonstrate the extent to which the <strong>in</strong>efficiency<br />

associated with a uniform contribution could be reduced with<strong>in</strong> the current <strong>in</strong>stitu-<br />

tional constra<strong>in</strong>ts. Table 2.6 presents the results of these simulations. The left-h<strong>and</strong><br />

panels present the market share, average enrollee risk, <strong>and</strong> the average <strong>in</strong>cremental<br />

contribution for each plan under five different pric<strong>in</strong>g scenarios. The <strong>in</strong>cremental con-<br />

tribution represents the monthly contribution per enrollee relative to the <strong>in</strong>tegrated<br />

HMO averaged across all households. The right-h<strong>and</strong> panels present <strong>in</strong>formation on<br />

the change <strong>in</strong> surplus relative to the observed allocation for each scenario.<br />

The Welfare Cost of Observed Prices<br />

In the top panels, we calculate the <strong>in</strong>efficiency of observed pric<strong>in</strong>g policies rela-<br />

tive to two risk-rated benchmarks. The first is <strong>in</strong>dividual risk rat<strong>in</strong>g based on the<br />

observed risk scores. This pric<strong>in</strong>g policy, which we refer to as “feasible risk-rated<br />

contributions”, maximizes social welfare conditional on knowledge of the risk scores,<br />

but not each household’s private <strong>in</strong>formation. The third panel of the Table reports<br />

outcomes when prices are first-best, i.e. risk-rated based on both <strong>public</strong> <strong>and</strong> private<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation.<br />

Overall, under risk-rated contributions, high-risk households face higher premiums<br />

<strong>and</strong> low-risk households face somewhat lower premiums for the network plans relative<br />

to observed contribution policies. In both the feasible <strong>and</strong> first-best scenarios, this


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 94<br />

leads to a substantial re-allocation of enrollees across plans, although overall market<br />

shares change modestly. With feasible risk-rat<strong>in</strong>g, the average enrollee risk at the<br />

<strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO <strong>in</strong>creases from its observed level of 0.99 to 1.49, <strong>and</strong> the network<br />

HMO experiences a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> average enrollee risk from 1.03 to 0.58. This reallocation<br />

of households across plans substantially reduces overall <strong>in</strong>surer costs, by $44 per<br />

enrollee-month, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>creases total social surplus by just over $27 per enrollee-month.<br />

The <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> social welfare represents approximately 11% of average <strong>in</strong>surer costs<br />

<strong>in</strong> our sample.<br />

A substantial fraction of the welfare ga<strong>in</strong> is due to the highest <strong>and</strong> lowest risk<br />

households mak<strong>in</strong>g more efficient plan choices. Table 2.7 decomposes the welfare<br />

calculation by household risk qu<strong>in</strong>tiles. The lowest <strong>and</strong> highest risk qu<strong>in</strong>tiles (aver-<br />

age household risk below 0.36 <strong>and</strong> above 1.33) generate about three-quarters of the<br />

welfare effect. This raises a concern that our calculation might be driven <strong>in</strong> part by<br />

extrapolat<strong>in</strong>g plan costs out of sample. As Figures 2.5 <strong>and</strong> 2.6 illustrate, we observe<br />

plan bids <strong>and</strong> costs only for average risk scores between 0.75 <strong>and</strong> 2.0. In contrast,<br />

household risk ranges from 0.16 to 30.1. To address this, we truncate the cost differ-<br />

entials between plans at their 0.75 <strong>and</strong> 2.0 levels <strong>and</strong> re-calculate the welfare numbers.<br />

These calculations appear <strong>in</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al columns of Tables 2.6 <strong>and</strong> 2.7. We view the<br />

numbers based on truncated cost differences as a lower bound on welfare differences,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the basel<strong>in</strong>e numbers based on straight-l<strong>in</strong>e extrapolation as closer to an upper<br />

bound. Truncat<strong>in</strong>g the cost differentials has little effect on the result<strong>in</strong>g assignment<br />

of households to plans, but as one might expect, it reduces the welfare cost of ob-<br />

served pric<strong>in</strong>g to $5 per enrollee-month, or 2% of <strong>in</strong>surer costs, relative to the feasible<br />

optimum.<br />

It is also <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to compare what is possible us<strong>in</strong>g prices based on observed<br />

risk scores to what <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple could be achieved us<strong>in</strong>g both observed risk scores <strong>and</strong><br />

households’ private <strong>in</strong>formation. This calculation captures the extent to which private<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation on risk constra<strong>in</strong>s the efficiency of feasible relative to optimal risk-rated<br />

pric<strong>in</strong>g. Chang<strong>in</strong>g from feasible risk rated contributions to the first-best scenario<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases social surplus by between $2 <strong>and</strong> $8 per enrollee-month, depend<strong>in</strong>g on the<br />

treatment of costs for extreme risk, or roughly 1-3 percent of <strong>in</strong>surer costs. One way


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 95<br />

to <strong>in</strong>terpret this is that, <strong>in</strong> our sample, a social planner could achieve approximately<br />

70% of the potential welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s associated with <strong>in</strong>dividualized pric<strong>in</strong>g us<strong>in</strong>g only<br />

observable <strong>in</strong>formation on risk.<br />

Social Welfare without Risk-Rat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

The calculations above <strong>in</strong>dicate that the observed prices fall well short of the effi-<br />

cient benchmark. A natural question is whether efficiency ga<strong>in</strong>s could be realized even<br />

without risk-rated contributions. That is, to the extent re-allocat<strong>in</strong>g high <strong>and</strong> low<br />

risk households would <strong>in</strong>crease social welfare, is it possible to <strong>in</strong>duce this reallocation<br />

given current <strong>in</strong>stitutional pric<strong>in</strong>g constra<strong>in</strong>ts? At first glance, the answer is unclear.<br />

After all, current <strong>in</strong>stitutions require uniform pric<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong> firm-tiers, but this still<br />

allows a fair amount of pric<strong>in</strong>g flexibility with<strong>in</strong> our sample. For example, average<br />

risk varies substantially across the firms <strong>in</strong> our data, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that cross-firm vari-<br />

ation <strong>in</strong> contribution policies could alleviate some of the <strong>in</strong>efficiency associated with<br />

uniform contributions.<br />

The next scenario <strong>in</strong> Table 2.6 addresses the question of what is possible with-<br />

out <strong>in</strong>dividualized pric<strong>in</strong>g by consider<strong>in</strong>g contributions that maximize social welfare<br />

subject to be<strong>in</strong>g uniform with<strong>in</strong> each firm-tier. As <strong>in</strong> the case of fully risk-rated<br />

prices, optimiz<strong>in</strong>g uniform with<strong>in</strong> firm contributions leads to a reallocation of high-<br />

risk households <strong>in</strong>to the <strong>in</strong>tegrated plans <strong>and</strong> away from the network plans, particu-<br />

larly the PPO. The shift is much less dramatic, however, than under full risk rat<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Overall social surplus is $1.40-6.70 higher per enrollee-month than under the observed<br />

policies, but still $3.60-20.40 below the efficient level. This <strong>in</strong>dicates that about 3/4<br />

of the observed <strong>in</strong>efficiency is due to the requirement of nondiscrim<strong>in</strong>atory pric<strong>in</strong>g<br />

with<strong>in</strong> firms. Nevertheless, it appears that employers could <strong>in</strong>crease social surplus<br />

by around 1-3% of average <strong>in</strong>surer costs simply by adjust<strong>in</strong>g their contributions to<br />

better reflect differences <strong>in</strong> underly<strong>in</strong>g plan costs.<br />

One difficulty for employers, of course, is that match<strong>in</strong>g contributions to plan<br />

costs may be a fairly complex exercise. Many benefits consultants, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediary <strong>in</strong> our data, suggest a simpler approach, which is to pass on the full<br />

<strong>in</strong>cremental premium for all but the lowest priced plan. We refer to this as the


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 96<br />

“Enthoven Rule”(?). About 1/2 of the firms <strong>in</strong> our sample use this approach for at<br />

least some workers. The last entry <strong>in</strong> Table 2.6 considers the effect of mov<strong>in</strong>g all<br />

the firms to an Enthoven-style approach. Perhaps surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, this has relatively<br />

little effect on overall welfare, or on household choices. The reason is that dem<strong>and</strong><br />

is not very price elastic <strong>and</strong> from a practical st<strong>and</strong>po<strong>in</strong>t most firms already pass<br />

through a substantial fraction of the premium differentials. So relative to the price<br />

changes needed to move substantial numbers of households across plans, a change to<br />

an Enthoven policy has only a modest effect on choices.<br />

This last observation raises an important po<strong>in</strong>t for our pric<strong>in</strong>g experiments. The<br />

relatively low elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong> means that the contribution differentials needed<br />

to re-allocate households <strong>in</strong> the direction of efficiency are sizeable. For <strong>in</strong>stance,<br />

maximiz<strong>in</strong>g welfare while keep<strong>in</strong>g contributions uniform with<strong>in</strong> firm-tiers would lead<br />

to some households see<strong>in</strong>g a $87 per-enrollee monthly premium for the network PPO<br />

relative to the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO. A move to efficient risk-rated prices would <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

this differential even more for some high-cost households. For <strong>in</strong>stance, an <strong>in</strong>dividual<br />

employee with a risk score of 3 would face a monthly premium differential of between<br />

$101 <strong>and</strong> $202 depend<strong>in</strong>g on our cost extrapolation. These large price differentials<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicate that achiev<strong>in</strong>g efficient allocations may raise issues of fairness or affordability<br />

of coverage for particular subgroups.<br />

2.5.3 The Value of Plan Choice<br />

By choos<strong>in</strong>g to offer benefits through the <strong>in</strong>termediary, each of the firms <strong>in</strong> our sample<br />

moved from offer<strong>in</strong>g a s<strong>in</strong>gle health plan to offer<strong>in</strong>g multiple plans from two carri-<br />

ers. A clear benefit of plan choice is that households with different preferences can<br />

select their preferred plan. Our estimates <strong>in</strong>dicate a substantial amount of preference<br />

heterogeneity, <strong>and</strong> hence suggest substantial welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s from giv<strong>in</strong>g households<br />

multiple plan options.<br />

To illustrate this, Table 2.8 compares aggregate surplus under the observed of-<br />

fer<strong>in</strong>gs to the surplus that would be obta<strong>in</strong>ed if all the households <strong>in</strong> our sample<br />

were enrolled <strong>in</strong> one of the four plans. The most natural benchmark is the <strong>in</strong>tegrated


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 97<br />

HMO, as it would be the most efficient s<strong>in</strong>gle-plan offer<strong>in</strong>g for every firm <strong>in</strong> our data.<br />

Relative to the <strong>in</strong>tegrated HMO benchmark, the observed plan offer<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong>crease so-<br />

cial welfare by almost $70 per enrollee-month for the firms <strong>in</strong> our data. Virtually<br />

all of this is due to an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> consumer surplus (gross of plan contributions)<br />

rather than to a reduction <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>surer costs. Indeed, <strong>in</strong>surer costs would be lowest if<br />

all households were enrolled <strong>in</strong> the network HMO but the reduction <strong>in</strong> social surplus<br />

would be large due the reduction <strong>in</strong> consumer surplus.<br />

One caveat to this calculation is the logit dem<strong>and</strong> specification is notorious for<br />

generat<strong>in</strong>g large “new product” welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s. Roughly speak<strong>in</strong>g, the problem is that<br />

each new product adds a new preference dimension, <strong>and</strong> some households <strong>in</strong>variably<br />

enjoy a large welfare ga<strong>in</strong> from this addition due to the logit distributional assump-<br />

tion. So while we th<strong>in</strong>k the benefits of plan choice are real, we urge some caution <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>terpret<strong>in</strong>g the magnitude of the measured effect.<br />

2.5.4 Discussion <strong>and</strong> Sensitivity Analysis<br />

Our estimates of market <strong>in</strong>efficiencies are based on a particular set of employers <strong>in</strong> a<br />

particular geographic area. One way to address external validity is to compare our<br />

estimates with some other studies of specific environments, such as ?, ?, <strong>and</strong> ?. These<br />

studies all rely on data from <strong>in</strong>dividual large employers, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> each case, the plans<br />

are plausibly dist<strong>in</strong>guished by their level of generosity, mak<strong>in</strong>g the environments a<br />

bit different from ours. All three studies f<strong>in</strong>d evidence that more generous plans are<br />

adversely selected. Cutler <strong>and</strong> Reber document this by us<strong>in</strong>g enrollee age as a proxy<br />

for risk. The latter two studies, like ours, use data on realized costs.<br />

Despite the difference <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional sett<strong>in</strong>gs, the bottom l<strong>in</strong>e welfare estimates<br />

from these studies are fairly similar, <strong>and</strong> also similar to our estimates. Cutler <strong>and</strong><br />

Reber estimate that observed prices at Harvard University reduce welfare by around<br />

2-4% of coverage costs relative to optimal uniform prices. E<strong>in</strong>av, F<strong>in</strong>kelste<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

Cullen estimate that <strong>in</strong> their sett<strong>in</strong>g average cost pric<strong>in</strong>g has a welfare cost of roughly<br />

2% relative to optimal uniform pric<strong>in</strong>g. Carl<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> Town f<strong>in</strong>d much smaller welfare


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 98<br />

effects, due to very low dem<strong>and</strong> elasticity. 23 Note that these papers all focus on<br />

uniform pric<strong>in</strong>g, which we have noted is generally <strong>in</strong>efficient except <strong>in</strong> special cases.<br />

When we use our estimates to compare observed pric<strong>in</strong>g to optimal uniform prices,<br />

we f<strong>in</strong>d welfare costs of approximately 1-3% of coverage costs. In this sense, there<br />

appears to be a fair amount of agreement between studies.<br />

As a group, these studies also re<strong>in</strong>force our earlier observation that <strong>in</strong>efficiencies<br />

from pric<strong>in</strong>g can be driven both by the nature of sort<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> risk-selection, <strong>and</strong> by the<br />

price elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong>, which determ<strong>in</strong>es the extent to which implicit subsidies or<br />

taxes affect choices. To guage the sensitivity of our own estimates to these factors,<br />

we recalculated the surplus difference between the observed <strong>and</strong> the feasible efficient<br />

allocation assum<strong>in</strong>g that dem<strong>and</strong> was twice as sensitive to price as we have estimated,<br />

<strong>and</strong> half as sensitive. We performed a similar analysis vary<strong>in</strong>g the risk sensitivity of<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>. These analyses <strong>in</strong>crease the range of the welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s to 1-13% of total<br />

coverage costs. Given the range of dem<strong>and</strong> estimates <strong>in</strong> the literature, one may want<br />

to assign a correspond<strong>in</strong>g range of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty to the potential welfare costs of price<br />

distortions.<br />

2.6 Conclusion<br />

Economists have long understood that competition <strong>in</strong> health <strong>in</strong>surance markets is no<br />

guarantee of efficiency. This paper contributes to a nascent literature that attempts<br />

to quantify market <strong>in</strong>efficiencies <strong>and</strong> identify their sources. A ma<strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g is that<br />

observed contribution policies distort enrollment decisions from their efficient level.<br />

We calculate that the welfare loss is on the order of 2-11% of the total cost of coverage.<br />

Captur<strong>in</strong>g these ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> full would require the use of risk-rated contribution policies.<br />

Absent such policies, optimally set employee contributions might <strong>in</strong>crease welfare by<br />

1-3% of coverage costs. A key po<strong>in</strong>t to emphasize is that despite these distortions,<br />

there appear to be substantial ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> our context from <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g plan choice at<br />

23 One explanation for their <strong>in</strong>elastic dem<strong>and</strong> estimate is that they rely on time-series variation<br />

<strong>in</strong> contributions. As discussed above, employees appear to be more price sensitive <strong>in</strong> mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>itial<br />

choices than <strong>in</strong> mak<strong>in</strong>g changes once they are enrolled.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 99<br />

the employer level.<br />

One important po<strong>in</strong>t about risk-rated premiums <strong>in</strong> health <strong>in</strong>surance is that cov-<br />

erage is typically purchased on an annual basis. While risk-rat<strong>in</strong>g might <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

static efficiency, it exposes households to reclassification risk as their health status<br />

changes over time. This is one argument for community rat<strong>in</strong>g or nondiscrimation <strong>in</strong><br />

employer contributions. It is <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to ask whether there are ways to promote<br />

static efficiency that nevertheless mitigate reclassification risk. One natural approach<br />

is to ensure that consumers have a basel<strong>in</strong>e option whose price is <strong>in</strong>dependent of risk,<br />

<strong>and</strong> allow <strong>in</strong>cremental purchases to be risk-rated. An alternative would be longer-<br />

term contracts that provide dynamic <strong>in</strong>surance (e.g., ?). Underst<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g the dynamic<br />

aspects of health <strong>in</strong>surance are an important challenge for future empirical work.<br />

2.7 Appendix to Chapter 2<br />

This Appendix compares our dem<strong>and</strong> estimates to the broader literature on health<br />

plan choice, <strong>and</strong> discusses alternative specifications of the consumer dem<strong>and</strong> model.<br />

2.7.1 Comparison to Dem<strong>and</strong> Estimates <strong>in</strong> Other Sett<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

As reported <strong>in</strong> Table 2.4, we f<strong>in</strong>d that on average a $100 dollar <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the annual<br />

enrollee contribution decreases market share by 7 to 9 percent. Studies <strong>in</strong> similar<br />

sett<strong>in</strong>gs vary <strong>in</strong> their method for report<strong>in</strong>g elasticities. Follow<strong>in</strong>g ?, we reconcile<br />

the estimates of price elasticity across studies by convert<strong>in</strong>g them to semi-elastiticies<br />

(calculated as the percent change <strong>in</strong> market share <strong>in</strong> response to a $100 <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

<strong>in</strong> the employee contribution). Because the studies cover different time periods, we<br />

adjust the change <strong>in</strong> the employee contribution for <strong>in</strong>flation. After mak<strong>in</strong>g these<br />

adjustments, most studies estimate semi- elastiticities <strong>in</strong> the range of -1.5 to -4.3 for<br />

the ma<strong>in</strong> specifications (????). Estimates from ? are somewhat higher (rang<strong>in</strong>g from<br />

-2.4 to -9.6 for the ma<strong>in</strong> specifications <strong>and</strong> even higher <strong>in</strong> some models). Similarly, ?,<br />

who analyze retirees, have an estimate that implies a semi-elastiticity of -9.0.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 100<br />

2.7.2 Alternative Specifications of the Dem<strong>and</strong> Model<br />

As we discuss <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> text, the estimates of risk <strong>and</strong> price elasticity are key<br />

parameters for our welfare calculations. Table 2.9 provides additional estimates of<br />

the dem<strong>and</strong> model to exam<strong>in</strong>e the sensitivity of these parameters. Column 1 of Ta-<br />

ble 2.9 repeats the first specification of Table 2.4 as a basel<strong>in</strong>e. This specification<br />

pools data from enrollees <strong>in</strong> different coverage tiers, <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the sample size <strong>and</strong><br />

generat<strong>in</strong>g additional variation <strong>in</strong> plan contributions due to the higher pass-through<br />

rates for dependent coverage tiers, but requires us to make assumptions about house-<br />

hold aggregation. We test whether our estimates are sensitive to these assumptions<br />

by restrict<strong>in</strong>g the sample to employees purchas<strong>in</strong>g employee-only coverage (Column<br />

2) <strong>and</strong> controll<strong>in</strong>g for family structure <strong>in</strong> our full-sample specification (Column 3).<br />

Both variations give similar results to our basel<strong>in</strong>e specification (Column 1). While<br />

the estimate of the effect of be<strong>in</strong>g a high risk <strong>in</strong>dividual on dem<strong>and</strong> for the network<br />

PPO is smaller <strong>in</strong> magnitude <strong>in</strong> the employee-only sample (Column 2), the estimate<br />

is imprecise likely because it is identified by a small number of enrollees. When we <strong>in</strong>-<br />

clude controls for family structure <strong>in</strong> the model estimated on the full sample, we f<strong>in</strong>d<br />

that families with a spouse seem to prefer the PPO relative to the average household<br />

(Column 3).<br />

As discussed <strong>in</strong> Section 2.5.4 , we develop different <strong>in</strong>struments to exploit alterna-<br />

tive sources of identify<strong>in</strong>g variation <strong>in</strong> employee contributions, test<strong>in</strong>g the robustness<br />

of our estimates to different exogeneity assumptions. In Table 2.4 (Columns 2 <strong>and</strong> 3),<br />

we demonstrate that the estimate of the price effect is robust to across-plan variation<br />

<strong>in</strong> employer contribution sett<strong>in</strong>g. To address the concern that employer contribution<br />

rates may be systematically <strong>in</strong>fluenced by employee preferences, we <strong>in</strong>strument for<br />

employee contributions with a variant of the contribution model <strong>in</strong> which the the<br />

pass-through coefficients are restricted to be identical across firms (Column 4). We<br />

view the concern that <strong>in</strong>surer bids are correlated with household preferences to be<br />

dim<strong>in</strong>ished because of the limited <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>surers have <strong>in</strong> our sett<strong>in</strong>g. Never-<br />

theless we report a specification where we <strong>in</strong>clude predicted bids <strong>in</strong> the contribution<br />

model (Column 5). The results from both these specifications are similar although<br />

with larger st<strong>and</strong>ard errors.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 101<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, we note that while we present results from a relatively parsimonious<br />

model, our estimates do not appear to be sensitive to <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g a variety of different<br />

control variables. Additional controls we have explored <strong>in</strong>clude plan out-of-pocket<br />

maximums, whether a plan was offered to an employer group prior to the employer<br />

hir<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>termediary, <strong>and</strong> the average health status of an employee’s co-workers.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 102<br />

Table 2.1: Risk <strong>and</strong> Demographics<br />

Mean Sd. M<strong>in</strong>. Max.<br />

Employees (N = 3683)<br />

Risk Score 1.21 1.56 0.18 30.06<br />

Age 40.56 12.01 18.00 72.00<br />

Female 0.62 0.48 - -<br />

Spouse 0.28 0.45 - -<br />

Child 0.27 0.44 - -<br />

Enrollees (N = 6603)<br />

Risk Score 1.01 1.45 0.14 30.06<br />

Age 32.13 17.67 0.00 72.00<br />

Female 0.58 0.49 - -<br />

Spouse 0.19 0.39 - -<br />

Child 0.26 0.44 - -<br />

Firm-Years (N = 16)<br />

Risk Score 0.97 0.31 0.63 1.91<br />

Age 31.67 4.63 25.71 46.09<br />

Female 0.53 0.12 0.30 0.70<br />

Spouse 0.19 0.07 0.08 0.27<br />

Child 0.26 0.08 0.06 0.39<br />

Employees 230.19 241.51 28.00 838.00<br />

Dependents 182.50 117.51 9.00 331.00<br />

Notes: In the first panel, spouse <strong>and</strong> child refer to the fraction of employees who enroll<br />

with a spouse or at least one child. In the second <strong>and</strong> third panels, these entries are the<br />

fraction of spouses <strong>and</strong> children <strong>in</strong> the set of enrollees. The first <strong>and</strong> second panels pool<br />

observations across firms <strong>and</strong> years. The third panel shows statistics of firm-year level<br />

averages, taken across all enrollees.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 103<br />

Table 2.2: Plan Characteristics<br />

Network Integrated<br />

HMO PPO HMO POS All<br />

Offer<strong>in</strong>g Plan<br />

Firms 11 10 11 9 -<br />

Firm-Years 16 14 16 13 -<br />

Bid (Monthly)<br />

Employee 307 332 260 276 294<br />

(64) (59) (30) (26) (54)<br />

Employee plus spouse 645 689 544 579 616<br />

(154) (123) (61) (54) (120)<br />

Employee plus child(ren) 591 632 498 532 565<br />

(143) (115) (58) (53) (111)<br />

Employee plus family 918 989 779 832 882<br />

(200) (176) (87) (76) (164)<br />

Contribution (Monthly)<br />

Employee 45 73 38 58 53<br />

(34) (54) (32) (40) (41)<br />

Employee plus spouse 252 303 203 255 253<br />

(120) (103) (77) (75) (100)<br />

Employee plus child(ren) 221 265 177 223 222<br />

(97) (86) (62) (55) (81)<br />

Employee plus family 418 495 342 415 418<br />

(213) (182) (144) (140) (176)<br />

Co<strong>in</strong>surance (%)<br />

Employee 87 86 97 78 87<br />

(6) (5) (7) (2) (9)<br />

Deductible (Annual)<br />

Employee 387 440 69 336 304<br />

(264) (306) (163) (94) (262)<br />

Out-of-Pocket Max (Annual)<br />

Employee 2818 2850 1591 2686 2468<br />

(462) (474) (625) (731) (775)<br />

Notes: Mean plan characteristics, with st<strong>and</strong>ard deviations <strong>in</strong> parentheses. Plan<br />

characteristics are pooled across years. Co<strong>in</strong>surance, deductible, <strong>and</strong> out-of-pocket<br />

maximum are <strong>in</strong>-network values <strong>and</strong> are highly correlated (ρ >.9) with out-of-network<br />

co<strong>in</strong>surance, deductible <strong>and</strong> out-of-pocket maximum. Coverage tiers based on employee<br />

plus one dependent <strong>and</strong> employee plus two or more dependents are used at two firms.<br />

Bids <strong>and</strong> costs for these coverage tiers are not shown.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 104<br />

Table 2.3: Risk <strong>and</strong> Demographics by Plan<br />

Network Integrated<br />

HMO PPO HMO POS All<br />

Employees (N=3683)<br />

Risk Score 1.19 1.22 1.22 1.19 1.21<br />

Age 42.17 40.79 39.73 41.35 40.56<br />

Female 0.62 0.52 0.65 0.56 0.62<br />

Market Share (%) 22.94 7.38 58.72 10.96 100<br />

Enrollees (N=6603)<br />

Risk Score 1.02 1.04 0.99 1.05 1.01<br />

Age 34.19 33.06 30.94 34.12 32.15<br />

Female 0.58 0.54 0.59 0.55 0.58<br />

Market Share (%) 21.24 7.84 60.35 10.57 100<br />

Notes: Employees <strong>and</strong> enrollees are pooled across firms <strong>and</strong> years.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 106<br />

Table 2.5: Costs <strong>and</strong> Bids<br />

(1) (2)<br />

Network Insurer Markup 1.29 (0.12) 1.27 (0.07)<br />

Integrated Insurer Markup 1.08 (0.04) 1.07 (0.03)<br />

NHMO 218.42 (21.35) 195.08 (9.48)<br />

X (Risk Score - 1) 288.25 (86.05) 265.36 (30.29)<br />

X Co<strong>in</strong>surance 0.32 (0.94)<br />

NPPO 238.32 (22.65) 204.59 (9.82)<br />

X (Risk Score - 1) 174.92 (34.34) 167.73 (23.81)<br />

X Co<strong>in</strong>surance 1.23 (1.29)<br />

IHMO 234.86 (9.71) 228.77 (6.77)<br />

X (Risk Score - 1) 73.67 (22.01) 104.80 (18.80)<br />

X Co<strong>in</strong>surance 0.38 (0.54)<br />

IPOS 236.37 (14.13) 216.74 (13.01)<br />

X (Risk Score - 1) 188.64 (69.35) 200.78 (61.60)<br />

X Co<strong>in</strong>surance 1.65 (0.82)<br />

N 91 91<br />

Notes: GMM estimates of cost parameters. See text for details. Co<strong>in</strong>surance is de-meaned<br />

at the plan level.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 107<br />

Table 2.6: Match<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Welfare under Alternative Contribution Policies<br />

Match<strong>in</strong>g Welfare † Truncated<br />

Gross Insurer Social Social<br />

NHMO NPPO IHMO IPOS Surplus ‡ Costs ‡ Surplus ‡ Surplus ‡<br />

Observed<br />

Market Shares 0.25 0.09 0.54 0.12 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

Risk Score 1.03 1.07 0.99 1.02<br />

Incremental Contribution † 9.30 23.70 0.00 5.00<br />

Feasible Risk Rated Contributions<br />

Market Shares 0.37 0.09 0.43 0.11 -16.60 -43.70 27.10 5.00<br />

Risk Score 0.58 0.78 1.49 0.74<br />

Incremental Contribution -14.70 11.80 0.00 -1.30<br />

Optimal Risk Rated Contributions<br />

Market Shares 0.38 0.08 0.44 0.10 -22.10 -57.50 35.50 7.80<br />

Risk Score 0.60 0.79 1.46 0.76<br />

Incremental Contribution -14.90 11.80 0.00 -1.60<br />

Uniform by Tier with<strong>in</strong> Firms<br />

Market Shares 0.31 0.09 0.49 0.12 -6.10 -12.80 6.70 1.40<br />

Risk Score 0.86 1.02 1.11 0.97<br />

Incremental Contribution -16.50 8.90 0.00 -1.10<br />

Enthoven Rule<br />

Market Shares 0.22 0.08 0.58 0.13 -1.10 -0.80 -0.30 -0.50<br />

Risk Score 1.01 1.05 1.00 1.02<br />

Incremental Contribution 28.70 39.90 0.00 10.80<br />

Notes: Feasible Risk Rated Contributions implements efficient match<strong>in</strong>g by sett<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>cremental contributions equal to <strong>in</strong>cremental costs, conditional on observable risk but<br />

not privately known risk. Optimal Risk Rated Contributions sets <strong>in</strong>cremental<br />

contributions equal to <strong>in</strong>cremental costs, conditional on both observable <strong>and</strong> privately<br />

known risk. Uniform by Tier with<strong>in</strong> Firms maximizes social surplus subject to the<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>t that contributions vary only by coverage tier <strong>and</strong> by firm, but not by <strong>in</strong>dividual<br />

risk. Enthoven Rule is implemented by sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>cremental contributions equal to<br />

<strong>in</strong>cremental bids. Reported risk score is conditional on plan choice. The truncated results<br />

holds cost differentials between plans for risk scores lower than 0.75 <strong>and</strong> higher than 2.0 at<br />

these boundary levels.<br />

† Incremental contribution, gross surplus, <strong>in</strong>surer costs, <strong>and</strong> social surplus are averaged<br />

across enrollees <strong>and</strong> denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> $ per month.<br />

‡ Gross surplus, <strong>in</strong>surer costs <strong>and</strong> social surplus are normalized to zero under the<br />

observed allocation. Other scenarios show gross surplus as social surplus relative to the<br />

observed allocation. Under the observed allocation, costs average $241.70 per enrollee per<br />

month. Gross <strong>and</strong> social surplus are not p<strong>in</strong>ned down.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 108<br />

Table 2.7: Match<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Welfare by Risk Score Qu<strong>in</strong>tile<br />

Feasible Risk Rated Contributions versus Observed<br />

Match<strong>in</strong>g Welfare Truncated<br />

∆Gross ∆Insurer ∆Social ∆Social<br />

Qu<strong>in</strong>tile (Risk Score range) NHMO NPPO IHMO IPOS Surplus Costs Surplus Surplus<br />

Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 1 (¡0.36)<br />

∆MarketShare 0.332 0.000 -0.330 -0.002 -27.2 -56.9 29.8 4.3<br />

∆IncrementalContribution -179.4 -93.4 0.0 -86.6<br />

Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 2 (0.36, 0.54)<br />

∆MarketShare 0.265 0.003 -0.266 -0.001 -16.6 -35.6 18.9 3.4<br />

∆IncrementalContribution -141.6 -75.9 0.0 -65.6<br />

Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 3 (0.54, 0.79)<br />

∆MarketShare 0.181 0.006 -0.189 0.002 -7.7 -17.1 9.3 1.3<br />

∆IncrementalContribution -99.1 -53.4 0.0 -44.6<br />

Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 4 (0.79, 1.33)<br />

∆MarketShare 0.040 0.004 -0.037 -0.007 -0.8 -2.4 1.6 0.4<br />

∆IncrementalContribution -21.0 -19.7 0.0 -1.2<br />

Qu<strong>in</strong>tile 5 (¿1.33)<br />

∆MarketShare -0.184 -0.047 0.299 -0.069 -30.3 -105.9 75.6 15.4<br />

∆IncrementalContribution 324.8 154.5 0.0 179.3<br />

Total<br />

∆MarketShare 0.128 -0.007 -0.106 -0.015 -16.6 -43.8 27.1 5.0<br />

∆IncrementalContribution -23.9 -11.9 0.0 -6.3<br />

Notes: ∆ Market Share, ∆ Incremental Contribution, ∆ Gross Surplus, ∆ Insurer Costs<br />

<strong>and</strong> ∆ Social Surplus are calculated as the difference between the feasible risk rated <strong>and</strong><br />

observed values of these variables. Truncated fixes cost differentials between plans for risk<br />

scores outside of 0.75 <strong>and</strong> 2.0. Values averaged across enrollees with<strong>in</strong> each qu<strong>in</strong>tile <strong>and</strong><br />

denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> $ per month. (Total values are averaged across all enrollees.)


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 109<br />

Table 2.8: The Value of Plan Choice<br />

Gross Surplus ‡<br />

Welfare †<br />

Insurer Costs ‡<br />

Social Surplus ‡<br />

Observed 0.0 0.0 0.0<br />

All enrolled <strong>in</strong>:<br />

NHMO -148.8 -9.2 -139.7<br />

NPPO -216.9 5.8 -222.7<br />

IHMO -71.4 -2.1 -69.4<br />

IPOS -180.7 4.5 -185.2<br />

Notes: † Gross surplus, <strong>in</strong>surer costs, <strong>and</strong> social surplus are averaged across enrollees<br />

<strong>and</strong> denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> $ per month.<br />

‡ Gross surplus, <strong>in</strong>surer costs <strong>and</strong> social surplus are normalized to zero under the<br />

observed allocation. Other scenarios show gross surplus as social surplus relative to the<br />

observed allocation. Under the observed allocation, costs average $241.70 per enrollee per<br />

month. Gross <strong>and</strong> social surplus are not p<strong>in</strong>ned down.


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 110<br />

Figure 1B: Efficient allocation assigns high-risk to plan A<br />

Figure 1A: Efficient allocation assigns high-risk to plan B<br />

"c(!)<br />

Value ($)<br />

Value ($)<br />

High-risk always self-select <strong>in</strong>to plan B.<br />

Choice of "p can <strong>in</strong>duce any threshold.<br />

No uniform "p generates the efficient<br />

allocation.<br />

"v(!)<br />

"v(!)<br />

High-risks always self-select <strong>in</strong>to plan B.<br />

Choice of "p can <strong>in</strong>duce any threshold.<br />

"p= "c( !* ) generates the efficient<br />

allocation of risk types across plans.<br />

"c(!)<br />

"p<br />

"p<br />

Efficiently <strong>in</strong> A<br />

Efficiently <strong>in</strong> B<br />

Efficiently <strong>in</strong> B<br />

Efficiently <strong>in</strong> A<br />

Consumer Risk (!)<br />

!*<br />

Consumer Risk (!)<br />

!*<br />

Figure 2B: Efficient allocation assigns high-risk to HMO<br />

Figure 2A: Efficient allocation assigns high-risk to PPO<br />

High (!,") always self-select to PPO.<br />

Choice of #p can <strong>in</strong>duce any translation<br />

of the pictured <strong>in</strong>difference curve.<br />

#v(!,")=#p<br />

Consumer<br />

taste for<br />

choice(")<br />

High (!,") always self-select to PPO.<br />

Choice of #p can <strong>in</strong>duce any translation<br />

of the pictured <strong>in</strong>difference curve.<br />

#v(!,")=#p<br />

Consumer<br />

taste for<br />

choice(")<br />

#v(!,")=#c(!)<br />

Choose<br />

HMO<br />

<strong>in</strong>efficiently<br />

Choose PPO<br />

efficiently<br />

Choose PPO efficiently<br />

Choose HMO,<br />

Efficiently <strong>in</strong> PPO<br />

Choose PPO<br />

Efficiently <strong>in</strong> HMO<br />

Choose HMO<br />

efficiently<br />

Choose HMO<br />

efficiently<br />

Consumer risk (!)<br />

!’ s.t<br />

#c(!’)=#p<br />

Choose #v(!,")=#c(!)<br />

PPO<br />

<strong>in</strong>efficiently<br />

Consumer risk (!)<br />

!’ s.t<br />

#c(!’)=#p


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 111<br />

Figure 2.3: Contributions <strong>and</strong> Bids Relative to Integrated HMO<br />

-50 0050<br />

50 100 150 200 -50 0050<br />

50 100 150 200 -50 0050<br />

50 100 150 200 -50 0050<br />

50 100 150 200 Employee Plus Spouse<br />

Employee Plus Spouse<br />

Network PPO<br />

Network PPO<br />

Network HMO<br />

Network HMO<br />

Integrated POS<br />

Integrated POS<br />

Y=X Incremental Contribution<br />

Incremental Contribution<br />

Incremental Bid<br />

Incremental Bid<br />

-50<br />

200<br />

Incremental Contribution<br />

0 50 100 150<br />

-50<br />

-50<br />

0<br />

Employee<br />

50<br />

100<br />

Network PPO<br />

Integrated POS<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

0<br />

-50<br />

150 200 -50<br />

Incremental Bid<br />

Employee Plus Spouse<br />

0<br />

50<br />

Network HMO<br />

Notes: Incremental Contribution <strong>and</strong> Incremental Bid are relative to Integrated HMO. In<br />

Employee Plus Spouse, numbers are divided by two for comparability.<br />

Y=X<br />

100<br />

150<br />

200


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 112<br />

Figure 2.4: Employer Contributions <strong>and</strong> Employee Characteristics<br />

0.2 .2 .4 .6 .8 .81 1Beta Beta .5 .51 1.5 2 2.5 Risk Score Risk Score 00.2<br />

.2 .4 .6 .8 .81 1Beta Beta 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 22Risk<br />

Score Risk Score 00.2<br />

.2 .4 .6 .8 .81 1Beta Beta 20000 30000 40000 50000 60000 Income 00.2<br />

.2 .4 .6 .8 .81 1Beta Beta 00500<br />

500 1000 1500 Number of employees<br />

Number of employees<br />

0<br />

Beta Risk Employee versus Score<br />

versus Employee Risk Beta Score<br />

Employee Plus Spouse Beta<br />

Employee Plus Spouse Beta<br />

versus Risk Score<br />

versus Risk Score<br />

Mean Beta versus Income<br />

Mean Beta versus Income<br />

Mean Beta versus Firm Size<br />

Mean Beta versus Firm Size<br />

Employee Beta versus Risk Score<br />

1<br />

.8<br />

Beta<br />

.4 .6<br />

.2<br />

0<br />

1<br />

.8<br />

Beta<br />

.4 .6<br />

.2<br />

0<br />

.5<br />

20000<br />

1<br />

30000<br />

1.5<br />

Risk Score<br />

Mean Beta versus Income<br />

40000<br />

Income<br />

2<br />

50000<br />

2.5<br />

60000<br />

1<br />

.8<br />

Beta<br />

.4 .6<br />

.2<br />

0<br />

1<br />

.8<br />

Beta<br />

.4 .6<br />

.2<br />

0<br />

0<br />

Employee Plus Spouse Beta<br />

versus Risk Score<br />

1<br />

1.2<br />

1.4 1.6<br />

Risk Score<br />

500 1000<br />

Number of employees<br />

1.8<br />

Mean Beta versus Firm Size<br />

Notes: Each po<strong>in</strong>t represents a firm-year. Beta is the <strong>in</strong>cremental pass-through of bids.<br />

See text for details. Employee Beta versus Risk Score plots the beta for employees aga<strong>in</strong>st<br />

their mean risk score. Employee Plus Spouse Beta versus Risk Score plots the beta for<br />

those <strong>in</strong> employee plus spouse plans aga<strong>in</strong>st their risk score. Scatter plots for other<br />

coverage tiers look similar. Mean Beta versus Income plots the mean beta (across<br />

coverage tiers) aga<strong>in</strong>st mean employee <strong>in</strong>come. Mean Beta versus Firm Size plots the<br />

mean beta (across coverage tiers) aga<strong>in</strong>st the number of employees <strong>in</strong> the firm. Separate<br />

scatter plots by coverage tier look similar.<br />

2<br />

1500


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 113<br />

600<br />

100 200 300 400 500 600 Costs .5 .51 1.5 2 2.5 Risk Score Risk Score Nework Insurer<br />

Nework Insurer<br />

Intergrated Insurer<br />

Intergrated Insurer<br />

100<br />

500<br />

400<br />

Costs<br />

300<br />

200<br />

100<br />

.5<br />

Nework Insurer<br />

Figure 2.5: Costs by Risk Score<br />

1<br />

Intergrated Insurer<br />

1.5<br />

Risk Score<br />

Notes: Each po<strong>in</strong>t represents a <strong>in</strong>surer-employer-year. Risk Score is the average enrollee<br />

risk score <strong>in</strong> a firm-year. Costs is the <strong>in</strong>surers’ monthly cost per enrollee. Fitted l<strong>in</strong>es<br />

represent the Network HMO <strong>and</strong> Integrated HMO.<br />

2<br />

2.5


CHAPTER 2. HEALTH PLAN CHOICE 114<br />

100 200 300 400 500 600 Bids .5 .51 1.5 22E[Risk<br />

Score|Age,Male]<br />

E[Risk Score|Age,Male]<br />

Network HMO<br />

Network HMO<br />

Network PPO<br />

Network PPO<br />

Intergrated HMO<br />

Intergrated HMO<br />

Integrated POS<br />

Integrated POS<br />

100<br />

600<br />

500<br />

Bids<br />

400<br />

300<br />

200<br />

100<br />

.5<br />

Network HMO<br />

Intergrated HMO<br />

Figure 2.6: Bids by Risk Score<br />

Network PPO<br />

Integrated POS<br />

1<br />

1.5<br />

E[Risk Score|Age,Male]<br />

Notes: Each po<strong>in</strong>t represents a plan-employer-year. E[Risk—Age, Male] is the average<br />

predicted risk score of potential enrollees <strong>in</strong> a firm-year. Bids is the per-month bid. Fitted<br />

l<strong>in</strong>es represent the Network HMO <strong>and</strong> Integrated HMO.<br />

2


Chapter 3<br />

Private Coverage <strong>and</strong> Public<br />

Costs: Identify<strong>in</strong>g the Effect of<br />

Private Supplemental Insurance on<br />

Medicare Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

with Marika Cabral<br />

3.1 Introduction<br />

In many <strong>in</strong>surance contexts, <strong>in</strong>dividuals hold primary <strong>and</strong> supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

policies for the same basic outcome. A common example is the purchase of pri-<br />

vate supplemental health <strong>in</strong>surance to top up <strong>public</strong>ly provided primary coverage. 1<br />

However, unlike st<strong>and</strong>ard markets where complementarities between products are<br />

typically isolated to the dem<strong>and</strong>-side, complementarities between primary <strong>and</strong> sup-<br />

plemental <strong>in</strong>surance can affect costs as well. A supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance policy that<br />

reduces the consumer cost-shar<strong>in</strong>g requirements (e.g., deductibles <strong>and</strong> co-payments)<br />

1 Other examples <strong>in</strong>clude disability <strong>in</strong>surance, where private coverage can supplement <strong>public</strong> disability<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance (SSDI) <strong>and</strong> rental car <strong>in</strong>surance, where coverage from a credit card can top-up the<br />

primary rental car <strong>in</strong>surance provided by a rental company.<br />

117


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 118<br />

of a primary <strong>in</strong>surance policy can affect total utilization, impos<strong>in</strong>g a fiscal externality<br />

on the provider of the primary <strong>in</strong>surance product.<br />

This paper estimates the effect of private supplemental Medigap <strong>in</strong>surance on pub-<br />

lic Medicare spend<strong>in</strong>g. Medicare is the primary <strong>in</strong>surer of elderly Americans, cover<strong>in</strong>g<br />

about 70 percent of the care they receive. To <strong>in</strong>sure aga<strong>in</strong>st the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g costs, most<br />

Medicare beneficiaries (91 percent) hold some form of supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance, which<br />

reduces out-of-pocket f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk but also blunts the cost-shar<strong>in</strong>g requirements of<br />

Medicare that are designed to limit utilization.<br />

To identify the effect of Medigap supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance on total utilization, we<br />

construct an <strong>in</strong>strument that leverages discont<strong>in</strong>uities <strong>in</strong> Medigap premiums at state<br />

boundaries. Medical costs, <strong>and</strong> thus the costs f<strong>in</strong>anced through supplemental Medi-<br />

gap <strong>in</strong>surance, exhibit considerable with<strong>in</strong>-state variation due to factors rang<strong>in</strong>g from<br />

household <strong>in</strong>comes to local physician practice styles to the supply of medical resources.<br />

Yet despite this local variation, with<strong>in</strong>-state variation <strong>in</strong> Medigap premiums is very<br />

limited (?). This means that on opposite sides of state boundaries, otherwise identical<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals who belong to the same hospital catchment area can face very different<br />

Medigap premiums solely due to Medicare costs <strong>in</strong> other parts of their states. Our<br />

empirical strategy uses this exogenous premium variation—<strong>and</strong> the correspond<strong>in</strong>g<br />

exogenous shift of <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> out of Medigap coverage—to identify the pre-<br />

mium elasticity of Medigap dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the causal effect of Medigap on total medical<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

The effect we identify is of substantial policy relevance. The high level <strong>and</strong> growth<br />

rate of Medicare spend<strong>in</strong>g makes it a primary concern of long-run US federal budget<br />

experts (?). Because of this, mechanisms that <strong>in</strong>crease costs <strong>and</strong> the correspond<strong>in</strong>g<br />

policies that could be used to address these ris<strong>in</strong>g costs are attract<strong>in</strong>g close atten-<br />

tion. However, as we discuss below, the current estimates of the effect of Medigap are<br />

biased due to selection on unobservables. This bias means that previous estimates<br />

may not reflect the behavioral responses to typical policies, such as a tax on Medi-<br />

gap premiums. Our approach overcomes these shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs allow<strong>in</strong>g us to explore<br />

economically mean<strong>in</strong>gful policy counterfactuals.<br />

In addition to the direct relevance for Medicare <strong>and</strong> Medigap policy, our study may


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 119<br />

be of <strong>in</strong>terest more generally. Sett<strong>in</strong>gs with private supplemental coverage <strong>and</strong> <strong>public</strong><br />

primary <strong>in</strong>surance are widespread. For example, <strong>in</strong> France more than 92 percent of<br />

the population holds private supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance to protect aga<strong>in</strong>st the substantial<br />

co<strong>in</strong>surance payments (10 to 40 percent) of the universal <strong>public</strong> health <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

system, <strong>and</strong> private supplemental policies that top up <strong>public</strong> health <strong>in</strong>surance benefits<br />

are popular <strong>in</strong> Austria, Belgium, <strong>and</strong> Denmark as well. 2 Yet despite economists’<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>teraction of <strong>public</strong> <strong>and</strong> private <strong>in</strong>surance as demonstrated by the<br />

large literature on crowd-out (cf. ??), there is relatively little work on the fiscal<br />

externalities associated with jo<strong>in</strong>tly held private <strong>and</strong> <strong>public</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance. 3<br />

At a conceptual level, supplemental Medigap coverage could impose a negative or<br />

positive fiscal externality on Medicare. Because Medigap policies reduce the marg<strong>in</strong>al<br />

price for care, it is straightforward to see that overall utilization <strong>and</strong> Medicare costs<br />

could <strong>in</strong>crease. Medigap policies could alternatively decrease costs if, for example,<br />

reduced cost-shar<strong>in</strong>g improved treatment adherence, reduc<strong>in</strong>g the risk of hospitaliza-<br />

tion. In the context of Medicare supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance available to retired California<br />

state employees, ? f<strong>in</strong>d there is a significant positive cost externality of supplemental<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance, what they call an “offset effect,” for those that are chronically ill. 4 For<br />

the overall retiree population, however, the externality is negative with supplemental<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g Medicare costs.<br />

The conventional wisdom is that supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance on net imposes a negative<br />

fiscal externality on Medicare, although the magnitude of the effect is contended. The<br />

central estimate, used by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) for official budget<br />

2 Statistics are from the follow<strong>in</strong>g sources: ? “Selected European Countries Health Systems,” <strong>and</strong><br />

? “The Grass Is Not Always Greener: A Look at National Health Care Systems Around the World”<br />

Cato Policy Analysis no. 613. In Austria, about a third of the population has a supplemental private<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance plan that covers additional charges not covered under the basic benefits, <strong>and</strong> about 30<br />

percent of Belgians carry private supplemental policies. Approximately 30 percent of population<br />

<strong>in</strong> Denmark purchases Voluntary Health Insurance (VHI) <strong>in</strong> order to cover the costs of statutory<br />

copayments of the universal coverage package.<br />

3 Exceptions <strong>in</strong>clude ?, ?, <strong>and</strong> ? on supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance.<br />

4 The authors argue that drug coverage is probably the s<strong>in</strong>gle most important channel through<br />

with the offset operates for the chronically ill. Even though the time period we look at is before<br />

Medicare Part D drug coverage was added, Medigap options that had drug coverage were very<br />

unpopular as their premiums were very high. Thus, we may expect the even among the chronically<br />

ill, Medigap private supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance may not have the offset effect the authors observe <strong>in</strong><br />

the CALPERs population.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 120<br />

estimates, is that “Medigap policyholders use at least 25 percent more services than<br />

Medicare enrollees who have no supplemental coverage.” Yet, as po<strong>in</strong>ted out by ?, the<br />

research CBO draws upon does not account for selection <strong>in</strong> Medigap enrollment <strong>and</strong><br />

may be biased. In particular, Lemiuex et al. argue that selection is probably adverse,<br />

lead<strong>in</strong>g these studies to overestimate the impact of Medigap on costs. Recent work,<br />

however, f<strong>in</strong>ds little or no evidence of adverse selection <strong>in</strong>to Medigap. 5 In fact, Fang<br />

et al. (2008) f<strong>in</strong>d evidence of significant advantageous selection <strong>in</strong>to Medigap. The<br />

authors argue that this advantageous selection is driven by cognitive ability, which is<br />

correlated with better health.<br />

We view our study as a natural next step <strong>in</strong> this literature. Our approach addresses<br />

the issue of selection by us<strong>in</strong>g plausibly exogenous variation <strong>in</strong> Medigap premiums.<br />

In particular, we take advantage of the fact that there is substantial with<strong>in</strong>-state<br />

variation costs but limited with<strong>in</strong>-state variation <strong>in</strong> premiums <strong>in</strong> the Medigap market.<br />

Us<strong>in</strong>g local medical costs as a control, we f<strong>in</strong>d that with<strong>in</strong>-state but out of locality<br />

medical costs are a powerful predictor of premiums, provid<strong>in</strong>g us with a source of<br />

premium variation that is unrelated to unobserved determ<strong>in</strong>ants of <strong>in</strong>dividual medical<br />

costs. We estimate a Medigap selection equation us<strong>in</strong>g this variation to identify the<br />

premium elasticity of Medigap dem<strong>and</strong>. Us<strong>in</strong>g the predicted values from this selection<br />

equation to <strong>in</strong>strument for Medigap enrollment, we consistently estimate the impact<br />

of Medigap on medical utilization.<br />

Our ma<strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g is Medigap coverage <strong>in</strong>creases overall medical costs by 57 percent<br />

on the marg<strong>in</strong>. The effect is about 40 percent larger than comparable OLS estimates,<br />

consistent with advantageous selection. We also f<strong>in</strong>d that Medigap dem<strong>and</strong> is mod-<br />

erately elastic, with our preferred estimate <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that a 10 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong><br />

premiums reduces take-up by 4.7 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts. Both the Medigap effect <strong>and</strong><br />

dem<strong>and</strong> semi-elasticity are precisely estimated <strong>and</strong> robust to alternative functional<br />

forms <strong>and</strong> sets of controls.<br />

In addition to <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g advantageous selection, the 40 percent larger <strong>in</strong>strumen-<br />

tal variables estimates for the effect of Medigap are consistent with heightened moral<br />

5 These papers <strong>in</strong>clude ?, ?, ?, <strong>and</strong> ?.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 121<br />

hazard for <strong>in</strong>dividuals on the marg<strong>in</strong> of Medigap choice. S<strong>in</strong>ce these marg<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>di-<br />

viduals are more price sensitive when it comes to premiums, it is natural for them to<br />

be more sensitive to the cost-shar<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>struments of Medigap, suggest<strong>in</strong>g larger ef-<br />

fects for these marg<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>dividuals than the average Medigap policyholder. 6 For our<br />

purposes, this feature is a strength of our empirical strategy rather than a weakness.<br />

The effect for <strong>in</strong>dividuals marg<strong>in</strong>al to a change <strong>in</strong> premiums is the effect of <strong>in</strong>terest<br />

for counterfactuals <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g a premium tax or subsidy, as the <strong>in</strong>dividuals identify<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the estimated effect are exactly those who would be affected by such a policy.<br />

We construct back-of-the-envelope policy counterfactuals of taxes <strong>and</strong> subsidies to<br />

Medigap premiums us<strong>in</strong>g our estimated parameters. A 20 percent tax would reduce<br />

coverage by 9.5 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts, imply<strong>in</strong>g a total budgetary sav<strong>in</strong>gs of 6.2 percent of<br />

Medicare costs of the sample. About 1/4 of the sav<strong>in</strong>gs would come from tax revenues<br />

<strong>and</strong> 3/4 from reduced medical costs. A 40 percent tax would save 11.4 percent <strong>and</strong><br />

a Pigovian tax that fully accounts for the negative fiscal externality would generate<br />

sav<strong>in</strong>gs of 18.1 percent. We note that our parameters are estimated us<strong>in</strong>g modest<br />

premium variation, <strong>and</strong> thus our policy counterfactuals, which <strong>in</strong>volve large taxes<br />

<strong>and</strong> subsidies, should be viewed with some caution. As we discuss below, a more<br />

nuanced tax policy that accounts for offsets might be able to generate both larger<br />

costs sav<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> better health.<br />

The rema<strong>in</strong>der of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 3.2 describes background<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation about Medicare <strong>and</strong> the supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance market. Section 3.3<br />

briefly describes the data used <strong>in</strong> our empirical analysis. Section 3.4 presents our<br />

empirical model. In Section 3.5 , we discuss our identification strategy. Results are<br />

presented <strong>in</strong> Section 3.6. Section 3.7 conta<strong>in</strong>s the policy counterfactuals. Section 3.8<br />

concludes.<br />

6 The <strong>in</strong>tuition for this relationship that suggests <strong>in</strong>dividuals at the marg<strong>in</strong> of select<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance based on premiums will be more sensitive to reductions <strong>in</strong> co<strong>in</strong>surance. A similar <strong>in</strong>tution<br />

is formalized <strong>in</strong> a model <strong>in</strong> a work<strong>in</strong>g paper by ?. In their paper, the authors refer to this sort of<br />

selection as “selection on moral hazard.”


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 122<br />

3.2 Background<br />

Medicare is the government health <strong>in</strong>surance program for elderly, cover<strong>in</strong>g nearly<br />

all <strong>in</strong>dividuals 65 <strong>and</strong> older <strong>in</strong> the United States. In 2008, Medicare covered 44<br />

million beneficiaries at a cost of $468 billion, account<strong>in</strong>g for about 13 percent of<br />

government expenditure <strong>and</strong> 3.2 percent of GDP. By 2025, Medicare is projected to<br />

cover 71 million beneficiaries, consum<strong>in</strong>g 20 percent of government expenditure <strong>and</strong><br />

5.5 percent of GDP. 7<br />

Medicare beneficiaries choose between <strong>public</strong>ly adm<strong>in</strong>istered traditional fee-for-<br />

service (FFS) <strong>in</strong>surance coverage <strong>and</strong> Medicare Advantage policies, private <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

plans with premiums subsidized by Medicare. 8 The majority (88 percent) of Medicare<br />

beneficiaries have FFS coverage. This coverage allows beneficiaries their choice of<br />

doctor <strong>and</strong> the ability to see a specialist without a referral. To control costs, fee-<br />

for-service Medicare uses cost-shar<strong>in</strong>g, expos<strong>in</strong>g beneficiaries to about 20 percent of<br />

the cost of care received on the marg<strong>in</strong>. A key feature of traditional Medicare is<br />

that there is no annual or lifetime out-of-pocket maximum amount that a beneficiary<br />

will pay, so <strong>in</strong>dividuals are exposed to significant f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk. Traditional Medicare<br />

cost-shar<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>struments for 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2005 (the first <strong>and</strong> last years of our sample)<br />

are shown <strong>in</strong> Table 3.1.<br />

To protect aga<strong>in</strong>st the f<strong>in</strong>ancial risk of traditional Medicare, the vast majority<br />

(91 percent) of beneficiaries carry supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance. Some beneficiaries obta<strong>in</strong><br />

supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance through a former employer, poor beneficiaries may qualify for<br />

supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance through the government sponsored Medicaid program, <strong>and</strong><br />

everyone else has the option to purchase private Medigap coverage. Medicare Ad-<br />

vantage is an alternative to traditional fee-for-service Medicare that is available to<br />

many beneficiaries. 9 These private <strong>in</strong>surance policies are subsidized by Medicare, <strong>and</strong><br />

7 Percent of GDP numbers are gross of premiums; percent of budget numbers are net (Annual<br />

Report of the Boards of Trustees of the Federal Hospital Insurance <strong>and</strong> Federal Supplementary<br />

Medical Insurance Trust Funds, 2010; Analytical Perspectives: Budget of the U.S. Government,<br />

2010).<br />

8 We will refer to Medicare Part C as Medicare Advantage <strong>in</strong> this paper, although this option was<br />

called Medicare + Choice dur<strong>in</strong>g the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the period we analyze.<br />

9 Although Medicare Advantage beneficiaries can technically sign up for Medigap policies, this is<br />

discouraged by Medicare <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividuals do not seem to do this <strong>in</strong> practice. Medicare Advantage


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 123<br />

have benefits that generally cover more services than offered <strong>in</strong> traditional Medicare<br />

<strong>in</strong> exchange for beneficiaries accept<strong>in</strong>g a more restricted network of providers. In our<br />

analysis, we model an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s choice between three options: Medicare Advan-<br />

tage, traditional Medicare without supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance, <strong>and</strong> traditional Medicare<br />

with supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance. In do<strong>in</strong>g this, we exclude <strong>in</strong>dividuals on Medicaid or<br />

employer provided supplemental health <strong>in</strong>surance. 10 Table 3.2 shows the breakdown<br />

of <strong>in</strong>dividuals on the various types of supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance.<br />

Medigap beneficiaries typically purchase Medigap <strong>in</strong>surance with<strong>in</strong> six months of<br />

turn<strong>in</strong>g 65 years old <strong>and</strong> sign<strong>in</strong>g up for traditional Medicare, dur<strong>in</strong>g what is called the<br />

open enrollment period. Dur<strong>in</strong>g this period, <strong>in</strong>dividuals cannot be denied coverage for<br />

any reason, <strong>and</strong> pric<strong>in</strong>g is limited to a small set of characteristics: gender, location,<br />

<strong>and</strong> smok<strong>in</strong>g status of the enrollee. 11 Plans bought dur<strong>in</strong>g this period are guaranteed<br />

renewable as long as Medigap enrollees pay plan premiums every year. The federal<br />

government regulates how Medigap policy prices can evolve. In particular, when<br />

an <strong>in</strong>dividual enrolls <strong>in</strong> a Medigap plan, he is choos<strong>in</strong>g an age-price profile that<br />

may be adjusted with medical <strong>in</strong>flation but may not be cont<strong>in</strong>gent on his current<br />

or future health status. Thus, along with the contemporaneous benefits, Medigap<br />

coverage provides <strong>in</strong>surance aga<strong>in</strong>st reclassification risk <strong>in</strong> future periods. In practice,<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals tend to sign up for a Medigap plan at age 65, <strong>and</strong> renew their policy each<br />

year. 12<br />

In most states, <strong>in</strong>dividuals choose from a menu of st<strong>and</strong>ardized plans labeled<br />

A through J, adm<strong>in</strong>istered by compet<strong>in</strong>g private <strong>in</strong>surance providers. 13 Table 3.3<br />

plans tend to give more f<strong>in</strong>ancial coverage <strong>in</strong> exchange for a more restricted network of providers relative<br />

to traditional Medicare. S<strong>in</strong>ce Medigap polices are tailored to fill gaps of traditional Medicare,<br />

the supplemental coverage that these policies would provide an <strong>in</strong>dividual on Medicare Advantage<br />

would be largely redundant.<br />

10 Those who are offered employer sponsored <strong>in</strong>surance typically receive a good deal <strong>in</strong> that the<br />

plans are very subsidized. S<strong>in</strong>ce we believe that the take-up rate on employer-sponsored <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

is nearly 100 percent, we excluded those on employer sponsored supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance from our<br />

analysis as they have a different <strong>and</strong> unobserved choice set.<br />

11 In practice, smok<strong>in</strong>g status is not priced dur<strong>in</strong>g the sample period we exam<strong>in</strong>e.<br />

12 This is the pattern we observe <strong>in</strong> the 3-year panel of the Medicare Current Beneficiary Survey.<br />

13 Massachusetts, Wiscons<strong>in</strong>, <strong>and</strong> M<strong>in</strong>nesota st<strong>and</strong>ardized their plans prior to federal regulation<br />

<strong>and</strong> have cont<strong>in</strong>ued their own offer<strong>in</strong>gs. The Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, <strong>and</strong> Modernization<br />

Act of 2003 (MMA) <strong>in</strong>troduced plans K <strong>and</strong> L <strong>and</strong> elim<strong>in</strong>ated the sale of Medigap plans<br />

with drug benefits (H, I <strong>and</strong> J).


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 124<br />

shows enrollment by plan letter <strong>and</strong> the plan characteristics <strong>in</strong> detail. Plans C <strong>and</strong><br />

F, by far the most popular plans, are chosen by over 60 percent of the Medigap<br />

beneficiaries. Both of these plans cover the hospital <strong>and</strong> physician deductibles, <strong>in</strong><br />

addition to the basic benefits common to all lettered plans. In this paper, we estimate<br />

the marg<strong>in</strong>al effect of the average Medigap plan, rather than the effect of particular<br />

plan characteristics. We believe the marg<strong>in</strong>al effect of Medigap captures a mean<strong>in</strong>gful<br />

concept <strong>in</strong> this context because the vast majority of <strong>in</strong>dividuals are on Medigap plans<br />

face the same marg<strong>in</strong>al change <strong>in</strong> prices. The common characteristics of the Medigap<br />

plans are ex ante the most likely drivers of moral hazard accord<strong>in</strong>g to previous studies.<br />

In particular, it is thought that physician expenditures is one of the most flexible<br />

marg<strong>in</strong>s of health care spend<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong> all plans <strong>in</strong>clude Part B physician co<strong>in</strong>surance<br />

coverage. 14 Part B co<strong>in</strong>surance coverage it thought to generate substantial moral<br />

hazard because it dramatically reduces the marg<strong>in</strong>al prices for doctor visits for almost<br />

everyone with physician expenditures. 15<br />

3.3 Data<br />

We have two primary sources of data. We use the Medicare Current Beneficiary<br />

Survey (MCBS) for 2000 through 2005. This data is a short panel of Medicare<br />

beneficiaries that <strong>in</strong>cludes cost data by payer, <strong>in</strong>formation about Medigap coverage,<br />

demographic <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>and</strong> relatively detailed health status variables. In addition<br />

to the MCBS data, we use Medigap premium data from Weiss Rat<strong>in</strong>gs. We obta<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

premium data for 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2003. This data <strong>in</strong>cludes premiums charged dur<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

open enrollment period by company, state, <strong>and</strong> plan letter. We use these two years<br />

of premiums to extrapolate premiums from 2000 to 2005. 16<br />

We match MCBS beneficiaries with the prices they faced at age 65. This means<br />

14 See ?.<br />

15 Because elderly <strong>in</strong>dividuals almost all have physician expenditures of 135 dollars annually (the<br />

approximate value of the Part B deductible), the marg<strong>in</strong>al price they face is the 20 percent co<strong>in</strong>surance<br />

rate for physician visits beyond this deductible. Compare this to the Part B deductible<br />

coverage, which is not available <strong>in</strong> all plans, but probably doesnt lead to much moral hazard.<br />

16 In particular, we assume a l<strong>in</strong>ear trend <strong>in</strong> premiums between 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2003. Us<strong>in</strong>g this trend,<br />

we project forward until 2005.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 128<br />

We use bootstrap methods to calculate the st<strong>and</strong>ard errors, loop<strong>in</strong>g over the entire<br />

set of equations for consistency.<br />

3.5 Identify<strong>in</strong>g Variation<br />

3.5.1 The Instrument<br />

The basic concept<br />

The idea of the empirical model is to use plausibly exogenous variation <strong>in</strong> Medigap<br />

premiums (equation 3.3) to shift <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> out of Medigap coverage (equation<br />

3.2) <strong>and</strong> thereby identify the impact of Medigap on total medical spend<strong>in</strong>g (equation<br />

3.1).<br />

To isolate variation <strong>in</strong> premiums that is conditionally r<strong>and</strong>om, we leverage discon-<br />

t<strong>in</strong>uities <strong>in</strong> Medigap premiums at state boundaries. As we discuss below, Medicare<br />

costs, <strong>and</strong> thus the costs of supplemental Medigap <strong>in</strong>surance, exhibit considerable<br />

with<strong>in</strong>-state variation due to factors rang<strong>in</strong>g from household <strong>in</strong>comes to local physi-<br />

cian practice styles to the supply of medical resources (????). Yet despite this local<br />

variation, with<strong>in</strong>-state variation <strong>in</strong> Medigap premiums is highly limited (?). 17 This<br />

means that otherwise identical <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>in</strong> otherwise identical localities can face<br />

sharply different Medigap premiums solely due to Medicare costs <strong>in</strong> other parts of<br />

their state.<br />

We put this idea <strong>in</strong>to practice by us<strong>in</strong>g state-level costs as an <strong>in</strong>strument while<br />

simultaneously controll<strong>in</strong>g for local costs <strong>in</strong> all the equations of our model. Controll<strong>in</strong>g<br />

for local costs is of course essential, as factors that <strong>in</strong>fluence costs <strong>in</strong> a local area almost<br />

surely <strong>in</strong>fluence costs <strong>and</strong> enrollment decisions <strong>in</strong> our sample, even conditional on the<br />

set of <strong>in</strong>dividual controls we <strong>in</strong>clude.<br />

17 Although firms are allowed to vary premiums at the zip code level, ? f<strong>in</strong>d there is very little<br />

with<strong>in</strong>-state variation <strong>in</strong> the Medigap premiums for a given plan offered by given <strong>in</strong>surance company.<br />

Maestas et al. cite state-level report<strong>in</strong>g requirements <strong>and</strong> regulations as a potential explanation.<br />

Because plans must, for example, meet loss ratio requirements at state level, vary<strong>in</strong>g premiums<br />

more locally may be adm<strong>in</strong>istratively burdensome. We discuss a robustness check to this issue <strong>in</strong><br />

Section 3.6.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 129<br />

Data <strong>and</strong> summary statistics<br />

In particular, we implement our <strong>in</strong>strumental variables strategy by us<strong>in</strong>g fee-for-<br />

service (FFS) Medicare cost data aggregated by the Dartmouth Atlas to the state<br />

<strong>and</strong> local level. 18 The advantage of the Dartmouth Atlas data is the methodology used<br />

to def<strong>in</strong>e local geographic areas. The Atlas aggregates cost data at two levels: the<br />

Hospital Service Area (HSA) <strong>and</strong> Hospital Referral Region (HRR). The HSA is the<br />

smaller unit of aggregation, def<strong>in</strong>ed by the set of zip codes whose residents receive most<br />

of their hospitalizations from hospitals <strong>in</strong> that area. These areas are approximately<br />

the size of a county: there are 3,446 HSA <strong>and</strong> 3,140 counties <strong>in</strong> the United States. To<br />

capture larger areas, the Dartmouth Atlas looks at where <strong>in</strong>dividuals are referred to<br />

for major cardiovascular surgery <strong>and</strong> neurosurgery. These are typically big, superstar<br />

hospitals, usual <strong>in</strong> big cities. HRR are more than 10 times as large as HSA: there are<br />

306 HRR <strong>in</strong> the country. To be conservative, we use larger HRR as the local area <strong>in</strong><br />

our analysis.<br />

Table 3.4 summarizes HRR level data on per capita FFS Medicare costs, tabulated<br />

by state. For expositional purposes, we show data from 2003, a year <strong>in</strong> the middle<br />

of our sample period. As is well known, there are vast differences <strong>in</strong> per capita costs<br />

between regions: costs range from $4,520 per capita <strong>in</strong> Salem, OR to $11,588 per<br />

capita <strong>in</strong> the Bronx, NY. A fact that is less well known, but vital to the power of<br />

our <strong>in</strong>strument, is that there are substantial differences <strong>in</strong> HRR-level costs with<strong>in</strong><br />

states as well. Per capita costs vary by more than $5,000 with<strong>in</strong> NY, FL <strong>and</strong> TX,<br />

<strong>and</strong> by more than $1,000 with<strong>in</strong> 25 states that are home to most (75 percent) of the<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>in</strong> our sample.<br />

Instrument power<br />

Figure 3.1 provides a concrete example of the power of our <strong>in</strong>strument. Panel A shows<br />

a map of per capita FFS Medicare costs <strong>in</strong> the states of New York <strong>and</strong> Vermont by<br />

HRR. Panel B shows Medigap premiums <strong>in</strong> the same two states. A comparison<br />

18 The Dartmouth Atlas data is constructed from the Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Medicare History Sample<br />

(CMHS), a 5 percent sample of the bill<strong>in</strong>g records Medicare beneficiaries collected by the Centers<br />

for Medicare <strong>and</strong> Medicaid Services (CMS).


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 130<br />

of costs <strong>and</strong> premiums <strong>in</strong> upstate New York <strong>and</strong> Vermont is illum<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g. While<br />

these two regions have almost identical per capita Medicare costs (no more than<br />

$5,864 <strong>in</strong> upstate NY versus $5,858 <strong>in</strong> VT), Medigap premiums <strong>in</strong> these regions are<br />

significant different ($1,677 versus $1,320). The bottom of the map shows why. New<br />

York state of course has New York City to its south, a region with substantially<br />

higher Medicare costs than the northern part of the state (maximums of $11,588 <strong>in</strong><br />

the south versus $5,864 upstate). It is the high cost metropolitan south, comb<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

with the limited with<strong>in</strong>-state variation <strong>in</strong> premiums, which <strong>in</strong>flates Medigap prices <strong>in</strong><br />

upstate New York without impact<strong>in</strong>g premiums <strong>in</strong> Vermont, creat<strong>in</strong>g an exogenous<br />

source of premium variation.<br />

To exam<strong>in</strong>e the statistical power of the <strong>in</strong>strument, we calculate the <strong>in</strong>cremental<br />

power – or partial R-squared – from add<strong>in</strong>g state costs to a regression of premiums<br />

on HRR-level costs. That is, we calculate the additional power from state costs<br />

when already controll<strong>in</strong>g for costs <strong>in</strong> the local region. As shown <strong>in</strong> Appendix Table<br />

3.10, a regression of log premiums on log HRR costs has an R-squared of 0.19 <strong>and</strong> a<br />

coefficient on HRR costs of 0.35. Add<strong>in</strong>g state costs reduces the coefficient on HRR<br />

costs to zero <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>creases the R-squared from 0.19 to 0.50, imply<strong>in</strong>g that 62 percent<br />

(=0.31/0.50) of the explanatory power of Medicare costs comes from outside local<br />

HRRs. The F-statistic on state costs is highly significant.<br />

3.5.2 Potential Concerns<br />

The exclusion restriction<br />

A key assumption underp<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g our empirical strategy is that, conditional on HRR-<br />

level costs, state-level Medicare costs only impact utilization through premiums <strong>and</strong><br />

Medicare choice. One potential concern with this assumption is that because <strong>in</strong>di-<br />

viduals travel outside their local HRRs to receive health care, the local measure of<br />

utilization is an <strong>in</strong>sufficient control. This concern is misplaced, however, s<strong>in</strong>ce local<br />

HRR costs account for travel, measur<strong>in</strong>g total utilization based on the location of<br />

residence regardless of where care is received. Thus, if <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>in</strong> one area tend<br />

to travel to another place with higher (or lower) costs for medical services, utilization


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 131<br />

levels <strong>in</strong> this area will reflect this propensity to travel.<br />

A more subtle concern is that the marg<strong>in</strong>al Medigap purchaser may be more<br />

(or less) likely to travel than the average Medicare beneficiary. If this is the case,<br />

then controll<strong>in</strong>g for average local health care utilization is <strong>in</strong>sufficient. Basically, the<br />

concern is that although most people <strong>in</strong> Rural Town, USA don’t travel to Big City,<br />

USA for care, the marg<strong>in</strong>al Medigap purchaser might be the type of person who does.<br />

A solution to this problem is to def<strong>in</strong>e markets broadly enough so that the closest Big<br />

City, USA is <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the market. We believe this is exactly what we do by us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

HRRs to def<strong>in</strong>e local markets as these regions are constructed explicitly to <strong>in</strong>clude<br />

the major hospital where people travel for sophisticated treatment.<br />

Therefore, given a measure of costs which accounts for travel <strong>and</strong> the conservative<br />

def<strong>in</strong>ition of local areas, we th<strong>in</strong>k that the exclusion restriction is unlikely to be<br />

violated. Nevertheless, if out-of-HRR costs did somehow directly impact costs, it<br />

would downwardly bias the coefficient on Medgap, work<strong>in</strong>g aga<strong>in</strong>st the direction of<br />

our ma<strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g. 19<br />

Medicare Advantage<br />

A f<strong>in</strong>al topic of discussion is our proxy for the price <strong>and</strong> availability of Medicare<br />

Advantage coverage: a second order polynomial <strong>in</strong> the county-year specific MA pene-<br />

tration rate. Controll<strong>in</strong>g for the determ<strong>in</strong>ants of MA enrollment is important for the<br />

explanatory power of the choice equation as Medigap <strong>and</strong> MA are typically viewed as<br />

substitutes. For similar reasons, it is important to <strong>in</strong>clude MA enrollees <strong>in</strong> the sample<br />

of analysis as MA coverage is the relevant alternative coverage to consider for changes<br />

<strong>in</strong> the Medigap market. Yet for valid estimation, the variables used to predict MA<br />

choice must satisfy the exclusion restriction of not directly impact<strong>in</strong>g medical costs.<br />

Below we make the case for their exclusion.<br />

The ma<strong>in</strong> argument for the exogeneity of county-year specific MA penetration<br />

rates is that much of the variation <strong>in</strong> this variable is driven by high-level federal<br />

19 In this case, higher out-of-HRR costs would simultaneously shift <strong>in</strong>dividuals out of coverage<br />

through the <strong>in</strong>strument <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>crease costs directly, creat<strong>in</strong>g a negative correlation between coverage<br />

<strong>and</strong> unobserved costs <strong>and</strong> bias<strong>in</strong>g downwards the coefficient on Medigap.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 132<br />

policy that could not plausibly be related to the unobserved component <strong>in</strong> the cost<br />

equation. MA penetration decreased over the first part of our sample as policies<br />

enacted <strong>in</strong> the 1997 Balanced Budget Act to reduce Medicare payments <strong>in</strong>directly<br />

decreased MA payments. MA penetration rates were then buoyed up by <strong>in</strong>creased<br />

payments written <strong>in</strong>to the 2003 Medicare Modernization Act (?). In addition, the<br />

goal of MA has shifted over time from promot<strong>in</strong>g efficiency to <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g broader goals<br />

such as regional equity mean<strong>in</strong>g there has been great variation over time <strong>in</strong> federal<br />

policy toward regional MA <strong>in</strong>surers. Thus most of the changes over time were driven<br />

by federal policy that could not be related to the unobservable.<br />

We also statistically test for the endogeneity of the county-year specific MA pen-<br />

etration variables. Recall that our Meidgap choice equation has two sets of excluded<br />

variables: Medigap premiums <strong>and</strong> the MA penetration variables. Based on the as-<br />

sumption that estimates from a specification us<strong>in</strong>g only Medigap premiums are con-<br />

sistent but <strong>in</strong>efficient <strong>and</strong> estimates from a specification with both Medigap premiums<br />

<strong>and</strong> MA penetration are efficient, a Durb<strong>in</strong>-Wu-Hausman test squarely fails to reject<br />

the exogeneity of MA penetration variables. In our preferred specification with the<br />

full set of controls, the test returns a Chi-squared value of 0.8, a value vastly below<br />

the 5 percent critical value of 37.6. Tests run on other specifications yield similar<br />

results.<br />

3.6 Results <strong>and</strong> Discussion<br />

3.6.1 Premiums <strong>and</strong> Medigap Choice<br />

Below we present basel<strong>in</strong>e estimates of the empirical model, start<strong>in</strong>g with the first<br />

stage premium equation, followed by the mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit second stage Medigap<br />

choice equations, <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ally the third stage cost equation. Each of these equations is<br />

estimated with three different sets of control variables. A sparse specification <strong>in</strong>clud-<br />

<strong>in</strong>g only key variables <strong>and</strong> year fixed effects; a specification that <strong>in</strong>cludes the demo-<br />

graphic controls; <strong>and</strong> a full specification that, along with the demographic variables,


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 133<br />

<strong>in</strong>cludes controls for health status such as self-reported health, <strong>in</strong>dicators of medi-<br />

cal diagnoses <strong>and</strong> treatment, <strong>and</strong> widely-used measures of functional status known as<br />

Activities of Daily Liv<strong>in</strong>g (ADL) <strong>and</strong> Instrumental Activities of Daily Liv<strong>in</strong>g (IADL).<br />

Table 3.5 presents the first stage estimates of Medigap premiums on state- <strong>and</strong><br />

HRR-level costs <strong>in</strong> logs. St<strong>and</strong>ard errors are clustered at the year-by-state level<br />

because premiums vary at this level. For the purposes of our policy counterfactual<br />

analysis, the most important parameter <strong>in</strong> this table is the elasticity of premiums<br />

with respect to state-level costs. This coefficient is 0.50 to 0.60 across specifications<br />

<strong>and</strong> precisely estimated (st<strong>and</strong>ard error of less than 0.07). As discussed <strong>in</strong> Section 3.5,<br />

most of the identify<strong>in</strong>g variation comes from state-level FFS Medicare costs. With<br />

HRR costs <strong>and</strong> the other controls, the F-statistic on state-level costs is well above<br />

the critical level.<br />

Marg<strong>in</strong>al effects for the probability of Medigap choice from the mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit<br />

choice equation are presented <strong>in</strong> Table 3.6. Recall that residuals from the premium<br />

equation are <strong>in</strong>cluded as a control variable to overcome the potential endogeneity of<br />

premiums. The premium semi-elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong> is estimated at a stable 0.38 to<br />

0.48 across specifications. (The premium elasticity estimates from the l<strong>in</strong>ear proba-<br />

bility model, shown <strong>in</strong> Appendix Table 3.11, are similar, rang<strong>in</strong>g from 0.31 to 0.42.)<br />

With demographic controls, the po<strong>in</strong>t estimates are significantly negative at more<br />

than the 5 percent level. In the preferred logit specification with the full set of con-<br />

trols (specification 3), we can reject any premium elasticity outside of 0.13 to 0.82<br />

with a 95 percent confidence <strong>in</strong>terval.<br />

Males are 3 percent less likely to purchase Medigap coverage. Medigap partici-<br />

pation is 20 percent lower for blacks, <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> education, but flat with respect<br />

to <strong>in</strong>come. Although we do not show it here, it should be noted that there is strong<br />

evidence that Medigap choice is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> factors the proxy for good health as<br />

well as underly<strong>in</strong>g cognitive ability (?).


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 134<br />

3.6.2 Causal Impact on Costs<br />

Table 3.7 presents estimates of the third stage cost model. Columns 1 through 3<br />

show simple OLS estimates of log total costs on a Medigap <strong>in</strong>dicator <strong>and</strong> controls;<br />

columns 4 through 6 show estimates with predicted values from the mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit<br />

model for Medigap choice used as <strong>in</strong>struments. The models are estimated with block<br />

bootstrap st<strong>and</strong>ard errors clustered by <strong>in</strong>dividual for consistency (?). In Appendix<br />

Table 3.12, we show 3SLS estimates of the cost equation us<strong>in</strong>g the l<strong>in</strong>ear probability<br />

model for Medigap choice.<br />

The OLS estimates (columns 1 to 3) suggest that Medigap coverage <strong>in</strong>creases total<br />

medical utilization by about 40 percent. With the full set of controls, a 95 percent<br />

confidence <strong>in</strong>terval allows us to reject any effect outside of 16 to 65 percent. The<br />

<strong>in</strong>strumental variables estimates are about 40 percent larger than the OLS estimate<br />

across the different sets of controls. With demographic controls (columns 5 <strong>and</strong> 6), the<br />

po<strong>in</strong>t estimates suggest that Medigap coverage causally <strong>in</strong>creases medical utilization<br />

by 57 to 61 percent for <strong>in</strong>dividuals local to the <strong>in</strong>strument. (The 3SLS estimates,<br />

shown <strong>in</strong> Appendix Table 3.12 <strong>in</strong>dicate effects of 59 to 63 percent.) In the logit<br />

specification with the full set of controls, a 95 percent confidence <strong>in</strong>terval allows us<br />

to reject any effect outside of 30 to 84 percent.<br />

We f<strong>in</strong>d it sensible that the <strong>in</strong>strumental variables estimates are larger than those<br />

estimated by OLS (57 versus 41 percent). As we have discussed elsewhere, Fang et<br />

al. (2009) f<strong>in</strong>d strong evidence of advantageous selection on a set of health variables<br />

that <strong>in</strong>crease the R-squared of their basel<strong>in</strong>e model from 7 to 21 percent. Yet even<br />

these controls leave 79 percent of the variation unexpla<strong>in</strong>ed. If there is some selection<br />

on <strong>in</strong>formation conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> this rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g variation, <strong>and</strong> this selection cont<strong>in</strong>ues to<br />

be advantageous, then we would expect an approach that overcomes this selection<br />

problem to yield larger estimates than a simple OLS approach.<br />

A second reason for why our basel<strong>in</strong>e estimates may be larger than the OLS<br />

estimates is because we are measur<strong>in</strong>g the moral hazard effect for <strong>in</strong>dividuals on the<br />

marg<strong>in</strong> of select<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to Medigap. The OLS estimates are best <strong>in</strong>terpreted as an<br />

average moral hazard effect that may be biased due to selection. In contrast, our<br />

basel<strong>in</strong>e logit estimates capture the moral hazard effect for <strong>in</strong>dividuals on the marg<strong>in</strong>


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 135<br />

of select<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to Medigap at current prices. These <strong>in</strong>dividuals are probably more<br />

price sensitive when it comes to premiums. If they are more sensitive to the price of<br />

medical care <strong>in</strong>duced by Medigap coverage as well, then the moral hazard effect for<br />

these marg<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>dividuals will be larger than the average Medigap policyholders.<br />

We th<strong>in</strong>k it is important to emphasize two th<strong>in</strong>gs about the <strong>in</strong>terpretation of our<br />

basel<strong>in</strong>e estimates related to this po<strong>in</strong>t. First, the moral hazard of <strong>in</strong>dividuals on the<br />

marg<strong>in</strong> is the precisely the parameter of <strong>in</strong>terested for policy analysis of a Medigap<br />

premium tax or subsidy. If the government levies, for example, a tax on Medigap<br />

premiums, then the <strong>in</strong>dividuals that select out of Medigap as a result of the tax will<br />

reduce their total medical care utilization by our basel<strong>in</strong>e estimate. (In Section 3.7,<br />

we demonstrate the effect of tax <strong>and</strong> subsidy policies us<strong>in</strong>g our estimates.) Second,<br />

one can view our moral hazard estimate as an upper bound on the moral hazard of<br />

all Medigap beneficiaries follow<strong>in</strong>g the logic that marg<strong>in</strong>al beneficiaries have greater<br />

moral hazard than <strong>in</strong>fra-marg<strong>in</strong>al beneficiaries.<br />

To compare our effect to other estimates <strong>in</strong> the literature, we follow st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

practices (??) <strong>and</strong> convert our po<strong>in</strong>t estimates to arc elasticities of expenditure (?).<br />

Under the approximation that Medigap decreases the “price” of a unit of healthcare<br />

from 0.2 to 0.0, the preferred po<strong>in</strong>t estimate of 0.57 implies an arc elasticity of 1.13.<br />

We th<strong>in</strong>k there are good reasons for why our estimate is higher than the “gold stan-<br />

dard” estimate of 0.22 from the RAND Health Insurance Experiment (HIE) of the<br />

1970s. The first is that our estimate may be local to particularly price sensitive <strong>in</strong>di-<br />

viduals, as discussed above. A second reason is that elderly people may be more price<br />

sensitive than the non-elderly population. While the RAND HIE only <strong>in</strong>cluded people<br />

under age 65, the Medicare population we study <strong>in</strong>cludes those over age 65. Other<br />

papers have found results consistent with the idea that the elderly have higher price<br />

elasticities of medical utilization (??). A third reason is that <strong>in</strong>novation <strong>in</strong> medic<strong>in</strong>e<br />

over the last 40 years could have affected price elasticities, perhaps by creat<strong>in</strong>g more<br />

treatment options for a given diagnosis that <strong>in</strong>dividuals can substitute among.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 136<br />

3.6.3 Robustness <strong>and</strong> External Validity<br />

Our first robustness check addresses the log specification for medical costs. It is well<br />

known that the skewed distribution of outcomes can create difficulties <strong>in</strong> estimat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

models with medical costs as a dependent variable. To show that the log specification<br />

we use is not driv<strong>in</strong>g the results, Panel A of Table 3.8 shows po<strong>in</strong>t estimates from the<br />

three-stage model where costs <strong>in</strong> the cost equation are denoted <strong>in</strong> levels. For com-<br />

parison, we divide these estimates by the average costs <strong>in</strong> our sample <strong>and</strong> display the<br />

results next to the estimated parameters from the model <strong>in</strong> logs. With demographic<br />

controls, the implied percentage changes <strong>in</strong> medical spend<strong>in</strong>g are similar to the log<br />

estimates (0.68 versus 0.57) although less precisely estimated.<br />

As discussed earlier, our analysis is restricted to the sample of <strong>in</strong>dividuals who<br />

turned 65 no sooner than the year 2000, as price data is not available from before<br />

this year. This, of course, means that the estimates should not be directly ascribed<br />

to the entire Medigap population because of potential age or cohort heterogeneity<br />

<strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> effect. However, we can shed some light on the external validity of the<br />

ma<strong>in</strong> results with simple OLS regressions. Panel B of Table 3.8 shows OLS estimates<br />

of log medical costs on a Medigap <strong>in</strong>dicator for the entire sample of <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>in</strong><br />

the data <strong>and</strong> the subset we analyze. With demographic <strong>and</strong> health controls, the OLS<br />

estimates from the samples are very similar (0.34 versus 0.37). However, to the extent<br />

that health controls may be partly determ<strong>in</strong>ed by Medigap choice, the specification<br />

with only demographic covariates may be more appropriate. The lower OLS estimate<br />

for the full sample <strong>in</strong> this specification (0.11 versus 0.35) suggests some caution when<br />

extrapolat<strong>in</strong>g the estimates of out sample.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, as discussed Section 3.5, there is <strong>in</strong> fact a small degree of with<strong>in</strong>-state<br />

variation <strong>in</strong> Medigap premiums <strong>in</strong> a small number of states <strong>in</strong> the sample (Maestas et<br />

al., 2009). To exam<strong>in</strong>e the robustness of the ma<strong>in</strong> results to this variation, we restrict<br />

our sample to states where, accord<strong>in</strong>g to Maestas et al., the with<strong>in</strong>-state coefficient of<br />

variation of Medigap premiums is less than 0.10 for 75 percent of firms issu<strong>in</strong>g plans. 20<br />

Panel C of Table 3.8 shows full model <strong>and</strong> OLS estimates of the coefficient on Medigap<br />

20 The states we drop are CA, FL, IL, LA, MI, NV, NY, PA, TX, <strong>and</strong> VA.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 137<br />

from the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>and</strong> restricted sample. The full model estimates are slightly lower<br />

(0.42 versus 0.57) although the ratio of full model to OLS estimates is very similar<br />

across samples. A possible reason for the lower full model <strong>and</strong> OLS estimates <strong>in</strong> the<br />

restricted sample is that the excluded states, which <strong>in</strong>clude states notorious for the<br />

overuse of medical services (e.g., FL, NY, TX), are states where the moral hazard from<br />

Medigap may be the largest. The premium semi-elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong> estimates, which<br />

are potentially the most susceptible to bias from with<strong>in</strong>-state premium variation, are<br />

almost identical across the restricted <strong>and</strong> basel<strong>in</strong>e samples.<br />

3.7 Policy Counterfactuals<br />

Hav<strong>in</strong>g shown that private Medigap <strong>in</strong>surance <strong>in</strong>creases medical utilization <strong>and</strong> thus<br />

Medicare costs by as much as 59 percent, it seems natural to consider corrective tax-<br />

ation. The idea of tax<strong>in</strong>g Medigap premiums is not new. In their 2008 chapter of<br />

budget options for health care, for example, the Congressional Budget Office (CBO)<br />

considered a 5 percent excise tax on Medigap premiums as a mechanism to reduce<br />

the federal deficit. As CBO po<strong>in</strong>ted out, an excise tax on Medigap premiums would<br />

reduce the deficit through two ma<strong>in</strong> channels: it would raise revenue from <strong>in</strong>dividuals<br />

who ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed their Medigap coverage while at the same time reduc<strong>in</strong>g Medicare<br />

costs for people who gave up their supplemental coverage. Yet the CBOs calculations<br />

of the taxs impact were likely based on a downwardly biased estimate of the effect of<br />

supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance, mean<strong>in</strong>g the CBO estimates of the effect of a tax underes-<br />

timated the budgetary effect. 21 In contrast, the parameters estimated here leverage<br />

plausibly exogenous variation <strong>in</strong> Medigap premiums, account<strong>in</strong>g not only for selec-<br />

tion on unobservable <strong>in</strong>dividual characteristics but also for potentially heterogeneous<br />

effects on <strong>in</strong>dividuals marg<strong>in</strong>al to a change <strong>in</strong> premiums.<br />

We use our estimated parameters to produce back-of-the-envelope budgetary es-<br />

timates <strong>in</strong> the follow manner: First, the counterfactual Medigap market share is<br />

21 In another section (Option 82) of their budget options volume, CBO cites studies claim<strong>in</strong>g<br />

that Medigap coverage <strong>in</strong>creases utilization by 25 percent versus <strong>in</strong>dividuals without supplementary<br />

coverage.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 138<br />

calculated us<strong>in</strong>g the estimated premium semi-elasticity of 0.475 (Table 3.6, specifi-<br />

cation 3) <strong>and</strong> assum<strong>in</strong>g the tax is completely passed through. 22 We estimate tax<br />

revenue by apply<strong>in</strong>g the tax to the result<strong>in</strong>g share of Medigap enrollees. Cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

are calculated by reduc<strong>in</strong>g the medical costs of <strong>in</strong>dividuals who drop Medigap by 37.0<br />

percent, the factor implied by the estimated parameter of 0.588 from specification 3<br />

of Table 3.7 (i.e., 0.370 =1 - 1/(1+0.588)). Medicare cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs are calculated as<br />

80 percent of this number, consistent with Medicare pay<strong>in</strong>g 80 percent on the marg<strong>in</strong><br />

for care. The total budgetary impact is simply the sum of the revenue <strong>and</strong> Medicare<br />

cost effects.<br />

Table 3.9 presents these revenue <strong>and</strong> cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs estimates for the st<strong>and</strong>ard sample<br />

of <strong>in</strong>dividuals with Medigap, Medicare Advantage, <strong>and</strong> no supplemental coverage.<br />

In this sample, basel<strong>in</strong>e Medigap enrollment is 35.8 percent, <strong>and</strong> Medical costs for<br />

Medigap enrollees average $9,458 per annum. The results are presented <strong>in</strong> dollars per<br />

beneficiary <strong>and</strong> as a percentage of Medicare costs of $5,528 on average for Medigap<br />

enrollees. A 20 percent tax would reduce coverage by 9.5 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts, rais<strong>in</strong>g<br />

1.3 percent of total costs <strong>in</strong> tax revenue <strong>and</strong> 4.8 percent of total costs <strong>in</strong> reduced<br />

utilization for total budgetary sav<strong>in</strong>gs of 6.2 percent. A 40 <strong>and</strong> 60 percent tax would<br />

save 11.4 <strong>and</strong> 15.6 percent of costs respectively. And a 76 percent tax, which would<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease Medigap premiums by $1,076, or about 50.5 percent of the implied $2,802<br />

(=0.37 x $9,458 x 0.80) externality, would reduce the Medigap market share to zero,<br />

sav<strong>in</strong>gs 18.1 percent of total costs entirely though decreased medical utilization.<br />

Although it probably goes without say<strong>in</strong>g, we rem<strong>in</strong>d the reader that the pa-<br />

rameters are estimated us<strong>in</strong>g local variation <strong>in</strong> premiums <strong>and</strong> the projected effects of<br />

larger taxes <strong>and</strong> subsidies should be viewed with appropriate caution. It is also worth<br />

mention<strong>in</strong>g that under current law, a tax that reduces FFS Medicare costs would re-<br />

duce m<strong>in</strong>imum Medicare Advantage payments. This is not taken <strong>in</strong>to account <strong>in</strong> our<br />

simple tax simulations, <strong>and</strong> would likely magnify the cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs we project.<br />

Last but not least, we want to call attention to the fact that a uniform tax on<br />

Medigap premiums is a blunt <strong>in</strong>strument for controll<strong>in</strong>g Medicare costs. Ch<strong>and</strong>ra et<br />

22 In the case of <strong>in</strong>complete pass-though, one can th<strong>in</strong>k of the counterfactuals as simulat<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

impact of tax that would give rise to the full pass-though <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> premiums.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 139<br />

al. (2007) have shown that targeted subsidies that reduce cost-shar<strong>in</strong>g for chronically<br />

ill Medicare beneficiaries can generate cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs or “offsets” by encourag<strong>in</strong>g treat-<br />

ment adherence <strong>and</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g unnecessary hospitalizations. A nuanced tax policy,<br />

which takes such effects <strong>in</strong>to account, might be able to generate both <strong>in</strong>creased costs<br />

sav<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> improved health.<br />

3.8 Conclusion<br />

In this paper, we have estimated the fiscal externality imposed by private Medigap<br />

supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance on <strong>public</strong> Medicare costs. We f<strong>in</strong>d that the moral hazard<br />

<strong>in</strong>duced by Medigap is substantial, with marg<strong>in</strong>al enrollees us<strong>in</strong>g 57 percent more<br />

services due to Medigap coverage. Policy counterfactuals reveal that a uniform tax<br />

that raises premiums 20 percent could generate comb<strong>in</strong>ed revenue <strong>and</strong> sav<strong>in</strong>gs of 6.2 of<br />

basel<strong>in</strong>e costs; a Pigovian tax that fully accounts for the fiscal externality could yield<br />

sav<strong>in</strong>gs of 18.1 percent. We are <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> the effects of more nuanced tax policies<br />

that account for “offsets” from treatment adherence or other positive externalities. In<br />

light of the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs of significant moral hazard from Medigap, we view the study of<br />

supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance around the world as an important topic for future research.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 140<br />

(10000,11000]<br />

(9000,10000]<br />

(8000,9000]<br />

(7000,8000]<br />

(6000,7000]<br />

[5000,6000]<br />

Figure 3.1: Example of Identify<strong>in</strong>g Variation<br />

(10000,11000]<br />

(9000,10000]<br />

(8000,9000]<br />

(7000,8000]<br />

(6000,7000]<br />

[5000,6000] <strong>and</strong> VT per capita Medicare costs<br />

(10000,11000] NY (9000,10000] <strong>and</strong> (8000,9000] VT (7000,8000] per (6000,7000] capita [5000,6000]<br />

Medicare NY costs<br />

NY <strong>and</strong> VT per capita Medicare costs<br />

(1600,1700]<br />

(1500,1600]<br />

(1400,1500]<br />

[1300,1400] NY <strong>and</strong> VT premiums<br />

(1600,1700]<br />

NY <strong>and</strong> VT premiums<br />

(1600,1700]<br />

(1500,1600]<br />

(1400,1500]<br />

[1300,1400]<br />

NY <strong>and</strong> VT premiums


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 141<br />

Table 3.1: Medicare Cost-Shar<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Part A: Hospital Expenditures Part B: Physician Expenditures<br />

Per day copayment<br />

SNF<br />

Per day copayment<br />

Year Deductible Days 61-90 Days 91-150* Deductible Co<strong>in</strong>surance Days 21-100<br />

2000 $776 $194 $388 $100 20% $97<br />

2005 $912 $228 $456 $110 20% $114<br />

*Medicare only pays for part A hosptializations <strong>in</strong> excess of 90 days through the drawdown of lifetime reserve days, of<br />

which beneficiaries have 60 over their lifetime.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 142<br />

Table 3.2: Summary Statistics by Supplemental Insurance Type<br />

ESI Medicaid Medigap MA None Total<br />

Enrollment<br />

N 16,477 6,594 11,830 13,045 4,475 52,420<br />

Percent<br />

Demographics<br />

31% 13% 23% 25% 9% 100%<br />

Male 43.1% 27.5% 33.8% 39.4% 42.0% 38.0%<br />

(0.4%) (0.5%) (0.4%) (0.4%) (0.7%) (0.2%)<br />

Age 75.0 77.9 76.4 74.7 77.1 75.8<br />

(0.1) (0.1) (0.1) (0.1) (0.1) (0.0)<br />

White 91.8% 71.1% 93.9% 85.5% 81.3% 87.2%<br />

(0.2%) (0.5%) (0.2%) (0.3%) (0.6%) (0.1%)<br />

College or more 22.6% 3.8% 15.1% 15.1% 10.5% 15.7%<br />

(0.3%) (0.2%) (0.3%) (0.3%) (0.4%) (0.2%)<br />

Income 37,818 10,839 30,215 30,691 20,887 29,490<br />

Utilization<br />

(371) (309) (439) (641) (431) (227)<br />

Total 11,008 25,456 10,152 8,062 18,169 12,511<br />

(147) (366) (167) (141) (409) (95)<br />

Medicare* 5,971 11,871 6,214 2,111 8,107 5,990<br />

(106) (258) (124) (79) (260) (64)<br />

ESI 2,907 113 14 182 132 988<br />

(37) (13) (2) (12) (17) (13)<br />

Medicaid 1 9,359 0 405 8 1,279<br />

(1) (176) (0) (36) (3) (29)<br />

Medigap 103 149 1,472 73 89 409<br />

(9) (11) (40) (5) (11) (10)<br />

Out-of-pocket 1,669 3,164 1,967 1,691 8,425 2,506<br />

(40) (72) (28) (43) (227) (29)<br />

Other 357 800 485 3,600 1,407 1,338<br />

(16) (51) (20) (85) (77) (24)<br />

Source: 2000-2005 MCBS<br />

Notes: ESI is employer sponsored supplmental <strong>in</strong>surance. MA is Medicare Advantage or Medicare+Choice as it<br />

was called <strong>in</strong> the beg<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g of the sample period. Sample excludes <strong>in</strong>dividuals with positive VA expenditure <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals resid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> states without Medigap coverage (MA, MN, WI). Payments from unexpected sources (e.g,<br />

Medigaid payments for ESI enrollees) due to switches <strong>in</strong> supplemental <strong>in</strong>surance type dur<strong>in</strong>g the year. St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses.<br />

*Does not account for Medicare capation payments to private plans


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 143<br />

Table 3.3: Medigap Enrollment <strong>and</strong> Plan Characteristics by Letter<br />

Medigap Letter<br />

A B C D E F* G H I J*<br />

Enrollment<br />

N 238 291 894 293 133 1,757 154 117 112 348<br />

Percent 6% 7% 21% 7% 3% 41% 4% 3% 3% 8%<br />

Plan Characteristics<br />

X X X X X X X X X X<br />

Basic benefits (Part A con<strong>in</strong>surance,<br />

Part B co<strong>in</strong>surance, blood, additional<br />

lifetime hospital days)<br />

Skilled nurs<strong>in</strong>g facility co<strong>in</strong>surance X X X X X X X X X<br />

Part A deductible X X X X X X X X X X<br />

Part B deductible X X X<br />

Part B excess charges X 80%<br />

Foreign Travel Emergecy X X X X X X X X X<br />

Home health care X X X X<br />

Prescription drugs X X X<br />

Preventive medical care X X<br />

Source: 2000-2005 MCBS<br />

Notes: Sample excludes <strong>in</strong>dividuals with positive VA expenditure <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividuals resid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> states without Medigap coverage (MA, MN, WI).<br />

*Plans F <strong>and</strong> J have a high-deductible option that requires beneficiaries to pay $1,580 before receiv<strong>in</strong>g Medigap coverage. These plans are rarely offered an<br />

have only 14 enrollees <strong>in</strong> the sample.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 144<br />

Table 3.4: HRR Level-Medicare Costs Tabulated By State<br />

State N Mean Std. Dev. M<strong>in</strong>. Max.<br />

NY 10 7,453 2,389 5,235 11,588<br />

NV 2 7,283 1,730 6,059 8,506<br />

FL 18 7,271 1,209 6,091 11,422<br />

MS 6 6,796 1,176 5,310 8,473<br />

CA 24 7,094 1,080 5,432 10,290<br />

TX 22 7,258 1,078 5,472 10,626<br />

IL 13 6,817 1,061 5,097 8,496<br />

MI 15 7,033 1,059 5,683 8,636<br />

PA 14 6,707 1,044 5,017 8,845<br />

LA 10 7,922 772 7,148 9,020<br />

UT 3 5,990 747 5,335 6,804<br />

IN 9 6,198 728 5,123 7,458<br />

NJ 7 8,626 713 7,216 9,426<br />

AR 5 6,162 691 4,983 6,709<br />

MA 3 8,123 621 7,431 8,631<br />

WI 8 5,355 620 4,587 6,304<br />

GA 7 6,160 534 5,068 6,852<br />

CO 7 6,112 516 5,211 6,767<br />

NH 2 5,785 487 5,440 6,129<br />

OR 5 5,049 466 4,520 5,547<br />

NC 9 6,165 456 5,563 6,955<br />

OH 10 6,932 455 6,385 7,674<br />

MO 6 6,106 445 5,541 6,634<br />

IA 8 5,063 420 4,690 5,814<br />

SC 5 6,430 404 6,043 7,065<br />

VA 8 5,770 374 5,275 6,312<br />

CT 3 7,864 369 7,527 8,258<br />

ND 4 5,315 356 4,902 5,677<br />

WA 6 5,716 352 5,170 6,108<br />

KY 5 6,439 331 6,088 6,807<br />

TN 7 6,641 307 6,374 7,026<br />

MN 5 5,544 298 5,193 5,876<br />

AZ 4 6,410 280 6,036 6,714<br />

AL 6 6,710 278 6,390 6,994<br />

ID 2 5,114 269 4,924 5,304<br />

MD 3 7,734 261 7,568 8,034<br />

ME 2 5,990 260 5,806 6,173<br />

OK 3 6,932 193 6,770 7,146<br />

SD 2 5,243 153 5,134 5,351<br />

KS 2 6,294 125 6,205 6,382<br />

NE 2 5,721 87 5,659 5,782<br />

MT 3 5,383 69 5,304 5,430<br />

WV 3 6,475 58 6,433 6,541<br />

AK 1 6,719 6,719 6,719<br />

DC 1 6,961 6,961 6,961<br />

DE 1 6,850 6,850 6,850<br />

HI 1 4,778 4,778 4,778<br />

NM 1 5,254 5,254 5,254<br />

RI 1 7,187 7,187 7,187<br />

VT 1 5,858 5,858 5,858<br />

WY 1 5,989 5,989 5,989<br />

Total 306 6,635 1,163 4,520 11,588<br />

Source: Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care<br />

Notes: Each observation is per capita FFS Medicare costs <strong>in</strong> a given HRR <strong>in</strong> 2003. The<br />

data is sorted by st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 145<br />

Table 3.5: First Stage: OLS Estimates of Premiums on State <strong>and</strong> HRR Costs<br />

(1)<br />

Dependent Variable: Log Premium<br />

(2) (3)<br />

Est. SE Est. SE Est. SE<br />

Log state cost 0.5020 (0.0583) 0.5990 (0.0686) 0.5950 (0.0678)<br />

MA penetration rate (%) 0.0004 (0.0018) 0.0000 (0.0018) 0.0001 (0.0019)<br />

MA penetration rate squared (%) 0.0000 (0.0000) 0.0000 (0.0000) 0.0000 (0.0000)<br />

Log HRR cost -0.0005 (0.0266) -0.0020 (0.0252) 0.0003 (0.0248)<br />

Male -0.0052 (0.0060) 0.0045 (0.0084)<br />

Age-65 0.0259 (0.0115) 0.0231 (0.0112)<br />

(Age-65)^2 0.0037 (0.0062) 0.0053 (0.0061)<br />

(Age-65)^3 -0.0007 (0.0009) -0.0010 (0.0008)<br />

Disabled eligibility<br />

Race group<br />

-0.0016 (0.0058) -0.0004 (0.0059)<br />

Asian 0.0149 (0.0141) 0.0121 (0.0134)<br />

Black 0.0097 (0.0118) 0.0114 (0.0116)<br />

Other<br />

Education group<br />

-0.0238 (0.0154) -0.0249 (0.0148)<br />

High school -0.0243 (0.0051) -0.0243 (0.0050)<br />

Less than college -0.0052 (0.0065) -0.0048 (0.0063)<br />

College or more -0.0094 (0.0073) -0.0113 (0.0070)<br />

Log <strong>in</strong>come 0.0007 (0.0028) 0.0011 (0.0028)<br />

Married -0.0104 (0.0050) -0.0102 (0.0053)<br />

Work<strong>in</strong>g 0.0026 (0.0054) 0.0015 (0.0055)<br />

Served <strong>in</strong> armed forces<br />

Self-reported health<br />

0.0136 (0.0064) 0.0122 (0.0067)<br />

Excellent -0.0042 (0.0119)<br />

Very good -0.0134 (0.0110)<br />

Good -0.0137 (0.0095)<br />

Fair -0.0209 (0.0096)<br />

Diagnosis <strong>in</strong>dicators Yes<br />

Treatment <strong>in</strong>dicators Yes<br />

IADL <strong>in</strong>dicators Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes<br />

R-squared 25.1% 31.2% 33.2%<br />

N 3,556 3,556 3,556<br />

F-statistic on log state cost 74.01 76.15 76.88<br />

Prob > F 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

Source: 2000-2005 MCBS; Weiss Rat<strong>in</strong>gs; Dartmouth Atlas<br />

Notes: Parameter estimates from OLS regressions of premiums on state- <strong>and</strong> HRR-level Medicare costs. The sample is restricted to<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals with Medigap, HMO or no supplemental coverage who turned 65 <strong>in</strong> 2000 or later. The omitted race group is white,<br />

education group is less than high school, <strong>and</strong> health status is poor. St<strong>and</strong>ard errors clustered at the state-by-year level <strong>in</strong> parentheses.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 146<br />

Table 3.6: Second Stage: Marg<strong>in</strong>al Effects for Medigap Choice from Mult<strong>in</strong>omial<br />

Logit Model<br />

(1)<br />

Marg<strong>in</strong>al Effects for Medigap Choice<br />

(2) (3)<br />

Mfx. SE Mfx. SE Mfx. SE<br />

Log premium -0.375 (0.214) -0.477 (0.220) -0.473 (0.221)<br />

Log premium residuals 0.398 (0.227) 0.532 (0.242) 0.531 (0.242)<br />

County MA penetration (%) -0.026 (0.002) -0.029 (0.002) -0.029 (0.002)<br />

County MA penetration squared (%) 0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000)<br />

Log HRR cost -0.049 (0.079) 0.002 (0.090) -0.009 (0.092)<br />

Male -0.028 (0.028) -0.029 (0.028)<br />

Age-65 0.061 (0.043) 0.065 (0.043)<br />

(Age-65)^2 -0.037 (0.020) -0.040 (0.020)<br />

(Age-65)^3 0.005 (0.003) 0.006 (0.003)<br />

Disabled eligibility<br />

Race group<br />

-0.010 (0.028) -0.013 (0.028)<br />

Asian 0.000 (0.068) 0.000 (0.069)<br />

Black -0.263 (0.026) -0.265 (0.026)<br />

Other<br />

Education group<br />

-0.025 (0.058) -0.028 (0.059)<br />

High school 0.038 (0.030) 0.041 (0.031)<br />

Less than college 0.126 (0.036) 0.130 (0.036)<br />

College or more 0.185 (0.039) 0.188 (0.042)<br />

Log <strong>in</strong>come -0.018 (0.013) -0.017 (0.014)<br />

Married 0.004 (0.024) 0.004 (0.024)<br />

Work<strong>in</strong>g 0.014 (0.029) 0.020 (0.029)<br />

Served <strong>in</strong> armed forces<br />

Self-reported health<br />

-0.033 (0.037) -0.033 (0.038)<br />

Excellent -0.094 (0.051)<br />

Very good -0.113 (0.052)<br />

Good -0.097 (0.049)<br />

Fair<br />

Diagnosis <strong>in</strong>dicators<br />

Treatment <strong>in</strong>dicators<br />

IADL <strong>in</strong>dicators<br />

-0.097 (0.050)<br />

Year FE Yes Yes<br />

Log pseudolikelihood/R-squared -15,205,864 -13,914,167 -13,853,769<br />

N 3,556 3,556 3,556<br />

Source: 2000-2005 MCBS; Weiss Rat<strong>in</strong>gs; Dartmouth Atlas, CMS State-County Penetration Files<br />

Notes: Marg<strong>in</strong>al effects for Medigap choice from mult<strong>in</strong>omial logit model with control function for Medigap premiums.<br />

Marg<strong>in</strong>al effects calculated at the sample means. For b<strong>in</strong>ary variables the predicted change <strong>in</strong> probability for a 0 to 1 change<br />

is shown. The sample is restricted to <strong>in</strong>dividuals with Medigap, HMO or no supplemental coverage who turned 65 <strong>in</strong> 2000 or<br />

later. The omitted race group is white, education group is less than high school, <strong>and</strong> health status is poor. Bootstrap<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard errors looped over the premium <strong>and</strong> choice equations <strong>and</strong> clustered by <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong> parentheses.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 147<br />

Table 3.7: Third Stage: OLS <strong>and</strong> Full Model Estimates of Medical Costs on Medigap<br />

Indicator<br />

Dependent Variable: Log Medical Costs<br />

OLS Full Model<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

Medigap 0.397 0.401 0.407 0.515 0.614 0.567<br />

(0.054) (0.053) (0.049) (0.158) (0.146) (0.138)<br />

Log HRR cost -0.071 0.233 0.128 -0.018 0.325 0.192<br />

(0.132) (0.134) (0.124) (0.173) (0.171) (0.164)<br />

Male -0.055 -0.071 -0.043 -0.049<br />

(0.061) (0.079) (0.074) (0.070)<br />

Age-65 0.817 0.904 0.810 0.890<br />

(0.125) (0.114) (0.126) (0.118)<br />

(Age-65)^2 -0.241 -0.299 -0.235 -0.278<br />

(0.072) (0.065) (0.065) (0.061)<br />

(Age-65)^3 0.023 0.030 0.021 0.027<br />

(0.010) (0.009) (0.009) (0.008)<br />

Disabled eligibility 0.419 0.333 0.422 0.346<br />

Race group<br />

(0.073) (0.067) (0.078) (0.074)<br />

Asian -0.314 -0.206 -0.292 -0.289<br />

(0.143) (0.136) (0.176) (0.175)<br />

Black -0.098 -0.171 -0.050 -0.148<br />

(0.090) (0.083) (0.113) (0.107)<br />

Other 0.034 -0.079 0.052 -0.057<br />

Education group<br />

(0.141) (0.131) (0.168) (0.155)<br />

High school 0.114 0.199 0.098 0.216<br />

(0.069) (0.064) (0.086) (0.082)<br />

Less than college 0.118 0.236 0.096 0.292<br />

(0.073) (0.069) (0.087) (0.083)<br />

College or more 0.184 0.347 0.156 0.404<br />

(0.084) (0.080) (0.103) (0.098)<br />

Log <strong>in</strong>come -0.012 0.049 -0.006 0.037<br />

(0.029) (0.026) (0.033) (0.030)<br />

Married -0.081 0.011 -0.090 -0.058<br />

(0.055) (0.052) (0.067) (0.062)<br />

Work<strong>in</strong>g -0.429 -0.168 -0.434 -0.250<br />

(0.060) (0.056) (0.066) (0.066)<br />

Served <strong>in</strong> armed forces -0.107 -0.119 -0.101 -0.091<br />

Self-reported health<br />

(0.080) (0.073) (0.098) (0.091)<br />

Excellent -0.616 -1.920<br />

(0.140) (0.138)<br />

Very good -0.565 -1.769<br />

(0.136) (0.133)<br />

Good -0.407 -1.392<br />

(0.129) (0.130)<br />

Fair -0.211 -0.890<br />

(0.130) (0.140)<br />

Diagnosis <strong>in</strong>dicators Yes Yes<br />

Treatment <strong>in</strong>dicators Yes Yes<br />

IADL <strong>in</strong>dicators Yes Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

R-squared 3.6% 11.1% 29.4% 3.4% 10.7% 19.9%<br />

N 3,415 3,415 3,415 3,415 3,415 3,415<br />

Source: 2000-2005 MCBS; Weiss Rat<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

Notes: Parameter estimates from cost equation. Specifications 1-3 show OLS estimates; 4-6 show estimates where<br />

Medigap choice is <strong>in</strong>strumed for with the predicted values from the logit cost equation. See text for details. Sample of<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals with HMO, Medigap or no supplemental coverage who turned 65 no sooner than 2000 exclud<strong>in</strong>g those with<br />

positive VA expenditure. Omitted race group is white, education group is less than high school, <strong>and</strong> health status is poor.<br />

Bootstrap st<strong>and</strong>ard errors looped over the premium <strong>and</strong> choice equations <strong>and</strong> clustered by <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong> parentheses.<br />

H_diabetes


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 148<br />

Table 3.8: Robustness Checks: Key Parameter Estimates from Alternative Specifications<br />

<strong>and</strong> Samples<br />

(1)<br />

Panel A: Levels versus Logs<br />

(2) (3)<br />

Levels<br />

Full model coefficient on Medigap <strong>in</strong> Levels 5829 (1850) 5705 (1572) 4978 (1520)<br />

Average Cost 7344 (339) 7344 (339) 7344 (339)<br />

Percent <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

Logs<br />

0.794 (0.252) 0.777 (0.214) 0.678 (0.207)<br />

Full model coefficient on Medigap <strong>in</strong> Logs 0.515 (0.158) 0.614 (0.146) 0.567 (0.138)<br />

Panel B: Full versus Analyzed Sample<br />

Full sample<br />

OLS Coefficient on Medigap<br />

Analyzed sample<br />

0.138 (0.020) 0.105 (0.020) 0.343 (0.017)<br />

OLS Coefficent on Medigap 0.379 (0.059) 0.352 (0.058) 0.370 (0.053)<br />

Panel C: Lowest Premium Variation States versus Analyzed Sample<br />

Lowest premums variation states<br />

Full model coeffiicient on Medigap 0.418 (0.207) 0.436 (0.188) 0.424 (0.178)<br />

OLS coefficient on Medigap 0.319 (0.083) 0.310 (0.081) 0.294 (0.077)<br />

Premium semi-elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong> for Medigap<br />

Analyzed sample<br />

-0.759 (1.589) -0.441 (1.546) -0.591 (1.525)<br />

Full model coeffiicient on Medigap 0.515 (0.158) 0.614 (0.146) 0.567 (0.138)<br />

OLS coefficient on Medigap 0.379 (0.059) 0.352 (0.058) 0.370 (0.053)<br />

Premium semi-elasticity of Medigap dem<strong>and</strong><br />

Controls <strong>in</strong> all panels<br />

-0.314 (0.187) -0.406 (0.160) -0.419 (0.158)<br />

Basic Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Demographic Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Health Controls Yes Yes<br />

Source: 2000-2005 MCBS; Weiss Rat<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

Notes: Parameter estimates for the effect of Medigap on total medical costs from various specifications. The sample is restricted to<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals with Medigap, HMO. Panel A shows estimates from the full three-stage model with total medical costs <strong>in</strong> levels <strong>and</strong> logs.Panel B<br />

presents estimates on the full sample <strong>and</strong> the analyzed sample restricted to <strong>in</strong>dividuals that turn 65 <strong>in</strong> 2000 or later. Panel C shows<br />

estimates of the ma<strong>in</strong> paramters from the subset of states with virtually no with<strong>in</strong>-state premium varition <strong>and</strong> the analyzed sample. The<br />

controls <strong>in</strong> specifications 1-3 match those <strong>in</strong> Table 7 specifications 1-3. Bootstrap st<strong>and</strong>ard errors clustered by <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong> parentheses.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 149<br />

Table 3.9: Policy Counterfactuals for Subsidies <strong>and</strong> Taxes of Medigap Premiums<br />

Tax Delta Medigap<br />

Tax revenue<br />

Medicare costs Budgetary effect<br />

% of premiums ppt $/beneficiary % $/beneficiary % $/beneficiary %<br />

-40.0% 19.0% -310 -5.6% 532 9.6% 843 15.2%<br />

-20.0% 9.5% -128 -2.3% 266 4.8% 394 7.1%<br />

20.0% -9.5% 74 1.3% -266 -4.8% -341 -6.2%<br />

40.0% -19.0% 95 1.7% -532 -9.6% -627 -11.4%<br />

60.0% -28.5% 62 1.1% -798 -14.4% -860 -15.6%<br />

76.0% -35.8% 0 0.0% -1,003 -18.1% -1,003 -18.1%<br />

Notes: Counterfactuals based on premium elasticity <strong>and</strong> Medigap estimates with full set of controls from Tables 6 <strong>and</strong> 7. Basel<strong>in</strong>e Medigap market<br />

share is 35.8 percent <strong>and</strong> premiums average $1,443. Medicare costs effect caculated assum<strong>in</strong>g Medicare pays for 80 percent of care on the marg<strong>in</strong>.<br />

Percent of costs calculated us<strong>in</strong>g Medicare costs of $5,528 on average for Medigap enrollees.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 150<br />

Table 3.10: OLS Estimates of Premiums on HRR- <strong>and</strong> State-Level Medicare Costs<br />

Dependent Variable: Log premium<br />

(1) (2)<br />

Log HHR costs 0.35 0.00<br />

(0.04) (0.04)<br />

Log state costs 0.63<br />

(0.04)<br />

R-squared 0.19 0.50<br />

N 290 290<br />

F-stat on log state costs 251.04<br />

Prob > F 0.00<br />

Source: Premium data from Weiss Rat<strong>in</strong>gs; Medicare expenditure data<br />

from the Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care<br />

Notes: There is one observation for each HRR where Medigap is offered.<br />

All variables are de-meaned. Premiums are for Plan C <strong>and</strong> all data is from<br />

2003. Robust st<strong>and</strong>ard errors are parentheses.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 151<br />

Table 3.11: Second Stage: 2SLS Estimates of Medigap Choice from L<strong>in</strong>ear Probability<br />

Model<br />

(1)<br />

Dependard Variable: Medigap Indicator<br />

(2) (3)<br />

Est. SE Est. SE Est. SE<br />

Log premium -0.314 (0.187) -0.406 (0.160) -0.419 (0.158)<br />

County MA penetration (%) -0.026 (0.002) -0.028 (0.002) -0.028 (0.002)<br />

County MA penetration squared (%) 0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000)<br />

Log HRR cost 0.002 (0.063) 0.104 (0.064) 0.091 (0.063)<br />

Male -0.050 (0.021) -0.117 (0.030)<br />

Age-65 0.046 (0.033) 0.038 (0.033)<br />

(Age-65)^2 -0.025 (0.017) -0.023 (0.017)<br />

(Age-65)^3 0.004 (0.002) 0.004 (0.002)<br />

Disabled eligibility<br />

Race group<br />

-0.019 (0.021) -0.015 (0.021)<br />

Asian 0.012 (0.049) 0.031 (0.053)<br />

Black -0.208 (0.024) -0.204 (0.025)<br />

Other<br />

Education group<br />

-0.040 (0.044) -0.050 (0.044)<br />

High school 0.083 (0.024) 0.085 (0.024)<br />

Less than college 0.153 (0.025) 0.156 (0.026)<br />

College or more 0.192 (0.032) 0.190 (0.033)<br />

Log <strong>in</strong>come 0.003 (0.010) 0.001 (0.009)<br />

Married 0.023 (0.019) 0.023 (0.020)<br />

Work<strong>in</strong>g 0.011 (0.022) 0.013 (0.022)<br />

Served <strong>in</strong> armed forces<br />

Self-reported health<br />

-0.020 (0.029) -0.022 (0.029)<br />

Excellent -0.108 (0.049)<br />

Very good -0.141 (0.048)<br />

Good -0.112 (0.045)<br />

Fair -0.092 (0.046)<br />

Diagnosis <strong>in</strong>dicators Yes<br />

Treatment <strong>in</strong>dicators Yes<br />

IADL <strong>in</strong>dicators Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes<br />

Log pseudolikelihood/R-squared 16.4% 20.4% 22.8%<br />

N 3,556 3,556 3,556<br />

Source: 2000-2005 MCBS; Weiss Rat<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

Notes: Parameter estimates from 2SLS estimates of l<strong>in</strong>ear probability model for Medigap choice. The sample is restricted<br />

to <strong>in</strong>dividuals with Medigap, HMO or no supplemental coverage who turned 65 <strong>in</strong> 2000 or later. The omitted race group is<br />

white, education group is less than high school, <strong>and</strong> health status is poor. Bootstrap st<strong>and</strong>ard errors clustered by<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong> parentheses.


CHAPTER 3. MEDIGAP 152<br />

Table 3.12: Third Stage: 3SLS Estimates of Medical Costs on Medigap Indicator<br />

(1)<br />

Dependent Variable: Log Medical Costs<br />

(2) (3)<br />

Log premium 0.495 (0.152) 0.630 (0.151) 0.585 (0.152)<br />

Log HRR cost -0.019 (0.165) 0.348 (0.171) 0.207 (0.171)<br />

Male -0.044 (0.072) -0.057 (0.102)<br />

Age-65 0.806 (0.128) 0.899 (0.114)<br />

(Age-65)^2 -0.232 (0.065) -0.295 (0.059)<br />

(Age-65)^3 0.021 (0.009) 0.029 (0.008)<br />

Disabled eligibility<br />

Race group<br />

0.421 (0.075) 0.325 (0.062)<br />

Asian -0.276 (0.175) -0.183 (0.179)<br />

Black -0.044 (0.110) -0.129 (0.110)<br />

Other<br />

Education group<br />

0.043 (0.182) -0.061 (0.152)<br />

High school 0.100 (0.079) 0.192 (0.076)<br />

Less than college 0.089 (0.080) 0.221 (0.075)<br />

College or more 0.159 (0.095) 0.335 (0.092)<br />

Log <strong>in</strong>come -0.007 (0.034) 0.054 (0.030)<br />

Married -0.081 (0.069) 0.016 (0.065)<br />

Work<strong>in</strong>g -0.435 (0.062) -0.172 (0.059)<br />

Served <strong>in</strong> armed forces<br />

Self-reported health<br />

-0.100 (0.100) -0.114 (0.096)<br />

Excellent -0.596 (0.137)<br />

Very good -0.547 (0.145)<br />

Good -0.387 (0.137)<br />

Fair -0.192 (0.129)<br />

Diagnosis <strong>in</strong>dicators Yes<br />

Treatment <strong>in</strong>dicators Yes<br />

IADL <strong>in</strong>dicators Yes<br />

Year FE Yes Yes Yes<br />

R-squared 3.5% 10.6% 29.1%<br />

N 3,415 3,415 3,415<br />

Source: 2000-2005 MCBS; Weiss Rat<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

Notes: Parameter estimates from 3SLS cost equation. Sample of <strong>in</strong>dividuals with HMO, Medigap or no supplemental<br />

coverage who turned 65 no sooner than 2000 exclud<strong>in</strong>g those with positive VA expenditure. Omitted race group is white,<br />

education group is less than high school, <strong>and</strong> health status is poor. Bootstrap st<strong>and</strong>ard errors clustered by <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong><br />

parentheses.


Chapter 4<br />

Do Expir<strong>in</strong>g Budgets Lead to<br />

Wasteful Year-End Spend<strong>in</strong>g?<br />

Evidence from Federal<br />

Procurement<br />

with Jeffrey Liebman<br />

4.1 Introduction<br />

Many <strong>organization</strong>s have budgets that expire at year’s end. In the U.S., most budget<br />

authority provided to federal government agencies for discretionary spend<strong>in</strong>g requires<br />

the agencies to obligate funds by the end of the fiscal year or return them to the Trea-<br />

sury general fund, <strong>and</strong> state <strong>and</strong> municipal agencies typically face similar constra<strong>in</strong>ts<br />

(???). 1<br />

For these <strong>organization</strong>s, unspent fund<strong>in</strong>g may not only represent a lost opportunity<br />

1 At the end of the federal fiscal year, unobligated balances cease to be available for the purpose<br />

of <strong>in</strong>curr<strong>in</strong>g new obligations. They sit <strong>in</strong> an expired account for 5 years <strong>in</strong> case adjustments are<br />

needed <strong>in</strong> order to accurately account for the cost of obligations <strong>in</strong>curred dur<strong>in</strong>g the fiscal year for<br />

which the funds were appropriated. At the end of the 5 years, the funds revert to the Treasury<br />

general fund.<br />

153


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 154<br />

but can also signal a lack of need to budget-setters, decreas<strong>in</strong>g fund<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> future<br />

budget cycles (??). When current spend<strong>in</strong>g is explicitly used as the basel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> sett<strong>in</strong>g<br />

budgets for the follow<strong>in</strong>g year, this signal<strong>in</strong>g effect is magnified.<br />

This “use it or lose it” feature of time-limited budget authority has the potential to<br />

result <strong>in</strong> low value spend<strong>in</strong>g—s<strong>in</strong>ce the opportunity cost to <strong>organization</strong>s of spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

about-to-expire funds is effectively zero. Exacerbat<strong>in</strong>g this problem is the <strong>in</strong>centive to<br />

build up a ra<strong>in</strong>y day fund over the front end of the budget cycle. Most <strong>organization</strong>s<br />

are de facto liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ed, fac<strong>in</strong>g at the very least a high cost to acquir<strong>in</strong>g mid-<br />

cycle budget authority. When future spend<strong>in</strong>g dem<strong>and</strong>s are uncerta<strong>in</strong>, <strong>organization</strong>s<br />

have an <strong>in</strong>centive to hoard. Thus, at the end of the budget cycle, <strong>organization</strong>s often<br />

have a buffer-stock of fund<strong>in</strong>g which they must rush to spend through.<br />

To illustrate the key mechanisms which create the potential for wasteful year-end<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g, we build a simple model of spend<strong>in</strong>g with fixed budgets <strong>and</strong> expir<strong>in</strong>g funds.<br />

Annual budget cycles are divided <strong>in</strong>to two six-month periods. Spend<strong>in</strong>g exhibits de-<br />

creas<strong>in</strong>g returns with<strong>in</strong> each period <strong>and</strong> is scaled by a productivity parameter that<br />

is unknown <strong>in</strong> advance. In the face of this uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, <strong>organization</strong>s engage <strong>in</strong> pre-<br />

cautionary sav<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> the first period. In the second period, the prospect of expir<strong>in</strong>g<br />

funds leads to a rush to spend. As a result, average spend<strong>in</strong>g is higher <strong>and</strong> average<br />

quality is lower at the end of the year.<br />

There is some suggestive evidence consistent with these predictions for the U.S.<br />

federal government. A Department of Defense employee <strong>in</strong>terviewed by ? describes<br />

“merchants <strong>and</strong> contractors camped outside contract<strong>in</strong>g offices on September 30th<br />

(the close of the fiscal year) just <strong>in</strong> case money came through to fund their contracts.”<br />

A 1980 report by the Senate Subcommittee on Oversight of Government Management<br />

on “Hurry-Up Spend<strong>in</strong>g” found that the rush to spend led to poorly def<strong>in</strong>ed contracts,<br />

limited competition <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>flated prices, <strong>and</strong> the procurement of goods <strong>and</strong> services<br />

for which there was no current need (?). At a congressional hear<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> 2006, agency<br />

representatives admitted to a “use-it-or-lose-it” mentality <strong>and</strong> a “rush to obligate”<br />

at year’s end (?). The 2007 Federal Acquisition Advisory Panel concluded that “the<br />

large volume of procurement execution be<strong>in</strong>g effected late <strong>in</strong> the year is hav<strong>in</strong>g a<br />

negative effect on the contract<strong>in</strong>g process <strong>and</strong> is a significant motivator for many of


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 155<br />

the issues we have noted with respect to, among another th<strong>in</strong>gs, lack of competition<br />

<strong>and</strong> poor management of <strong>in</strong>teragency contracts” (?).<br />

Yet despite these accounts, there is no hard evidence on whether year-end spend-<br />

<strong>in</strong>g surges are currently occurr<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the U.S. federal government or whether year-end<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g is lower-value than spend<strong>in</strong>g dur<strong>in</strong>g the rest of the year. Government Ac-<br />

countability Office (GAO) reports <strong>in</strong> 1980 <strong>and</strong> 1985 documented that fourth quarter<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g was somewhat higher than spend<strong>in</strong>g dur<strong>in</strong>g the rest of year us<strong>in</strong>g aggregate<br />

agency spend<strong>in</strong>g data. In a follow-up report, ? stated that because “substantial<br />

reforms <strong>in</strong> procurement plann<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> competition requirements have changed the<br />

environment . . . year-end spend<strong>in</strong>g is unlikely to present the same magnitude of<br />

problems <strong>and</strong> issues as before.” However, this later report was unable to exam<strong>in</strong>e<br />

quarterly agency spend<strong>in</strong>g patterns for 1997 because agency compliance with quar-<br />

terly report<strong>in</strong>g requirements was <strong>in</strong>complete. Other government professionals cite<br />

similar constra<strong>in</strong>ts to empirical analysis. In summariz<strong>in</strong>g the response of Department<br />

of Defense contract<strong>in</strong>g officers to the <strong>in</strong>terview question, “How would you measure<br />

the quality of year-end spend<strong>in</strong>g?” ? writes, “Absent flagrant abuse that no one<br />

could miss, there is no practical way of weigh<strong>in</strong>g year-end spend<strong>in</strong>g.”<br />

This paper address the empirical shortfall. It beg<strong>in</strong>s by document<strong>in</strong>g the with<strong>in</strong>-<br />

year pattern of federal spend<strong>in</strong>g on government contracts, the ma<strong>in</strong> category of spend-<br />

<strong>in</strong>g where significant discretion about tim<strong>in</strong>g exists. The analysis demonstrates that<br />

there is a large surge <strong>in</strong> the 52nd week of the year that is concentrated <strong>in</strong> procure-<br />

ments for construction-related goods <strong>and</strong> services, furnish<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> office equipment,<br />

<strong>and</strong> I.T. services <strong>and</strong> equipment. It also shows that the date of completion of annual<br />

appropriations legislation has a noticeable effect on the tim<strong>in</strong>g of federal contract<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

consistent with anecdotal claims that part of the difficulties agencies face <strong>in</strong> effective<br />

management of acquisitions comes from tardy enactment of appropriations legisla-<br />

tion. The estimates show that a delay of ten weeks, roughly the average over this<br />

time period, raises raises the share of spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the last month by 1 percentage<br />

po<strong>in</strong>t, from a base of about 15 percent.<br />

We then analyze the impact of the end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g surge on spend<strong>in</strong>g quality<br />

us<strong>in</strong>g a newly available dataset on the status of the federal government’s 686 major


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 156<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation technology projects—a total of $130 billion <strong>in</strong> spend<strong>in</strong>g. Consistent with<br />

the model, spend<strong>in</strong>g on these I.T. projects spikes <strong>in</strong> the last week of the fiscal year,<br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g to 7.2 times the rest-of-year weekly average. Moreover, the spike is not<br />

isolated to a small set of agencies or a subset of years, but rather a persistent feature<br />

both across agencies <strong>and</strong> over time. In t<strong>and</strong>em with the spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>crease, there<br />

is a sharp drop-off <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment quality. Based on a categorical <strong>in</strong>dex of overall<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment performance, which comb<strong>in</strong>es assessments from agency <strong>in</strong>formation officers<br />

with data on cost <strong>and</strong> timel<strong>in</strong>ess, we f<strong>in</strong>d that projects that orig<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>in</strong> the last week<br />

of the fiscal year have 2.2 to 5.6 times higher odds of hav<strong>in</strong>g a lower quality score.<br />

Ordered logit <strong>and</strong> OLS regressions show that this effect is robust to agency <strong>and</strong> year<br />

specific factors as well as to a rich set of project characteristic controls.<br />

Our f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs suggest that the various safeguard measures put <strong>in</strong>to place <strong>in</strong> re-<br />

sponse to the 1980 Senate Subcommittee report (?) <strong>and</strong> to broader concerns about<br />

acquisition plann<strong>in</strong>g have not been fully successful <strong>in</strong> elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g the end-of-year<br />

rush-to-spend <strong>in</strong>efficiency. An alternative solution is to give agencies the ability to<br />

roll over some of their unused fund<strong>in</strong>g for an additional year. Provisions of this nature<br />

have been applied with apparent success <strong>in</strong> the states of Oklahoma <strong>and</strong> Wash<strong>in</strong>gton,<br />

as well as <strong>in</strong> the UK (??). With<strong>in</strong> the U.S. federal government, the Department of<br />

Justice (DOJ) has obta<strong>in</strong>ed special authority to roll over unused budget authority<br />

<strong>in</strong>to a fund that can be used <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g year.<br />

We extend the model to allow for rollover <strong>and</strong> show that, <strong>in</strong> the context of the<br />

model, the efficiency ga<strong>in</strong>s from this ability are unequivocally positive. To test this<br />

prediction, we study I.T. contracts at the Department of Justice which has special<br />

rollover authority. We show that there is only a small end-of-year I.T. spend<strong>in</strong>g spike<br />

at DOJ <strong>and</strong> that the one major I.T. contract DOJ issued <strong>in</strong> the 52nd week of the<br />

year has a quality rat<strong>in</strong>g that is well above average.<br />

The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 4.2 presents a model of wasteful<br />

year-end spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> discusses the mechanisms that could potentially lead to end-<br />

of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g be<strong>in</strong>g of lower quality than spend<strong>in</strong>g dur<strong>in</strong>g the rest of the year.<br />

Section 4.3 exam<strong>in</strong>es the surge <strong>in</strong> year-end spend<strong>in</strong>g us<strong>in</strong>g a comprehensive dataset<br />

on federal procurement. Section 4.4 tests for a year-end drop-off <strong>in</strong> quality us<strong>in</strong>g data


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 157<br />

on I.T. <strong>in</strong>vestments. Section 4.5 analyzes the Department of Justice experience with<br />

rollover authority. Section 4.6 concludes.<br />

4.2 A Model of Wasteful Year-End Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

In this section, we present a simple model to illustrate how expir<strong>in</strong>g budgets can give<br />

rise to wasteful year-end spend<strong>in</strong>g. The model has three key features. First, there<br />

are decreas<strong>in</strong>g returns to spend<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong> each sub-year period. Decreas<strong>in</strong>g returns<br />

could be motivated by a priority-based budget<strong>in</strong>g rule, where dur<strong>in</strong>g a given period<br />

<strong>organization</strong>s allocate resources to projects accord<strong>in</strong>g to the surplus they provide.<br />

Alternatively, decreas<strong>in</strong>g returns could be motivated by short-run rigidities <strong>in</strong> the<br />

production function. For example, federal agencies with a fixed staff of contract<strong>in</strong>g<br />

specialists might have less time to devote to each contract <strong>in</strong> a period with abnormally<br />

high spend<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Second, there is uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty over the value of future budget resources. One can<br />

th<strong>in</strong>k of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty aris<strong>in</strong>g from either dem<strong>and</strong> or supply factors. Shifts <strong>in</strong> mili-<br />

tary strategy or an <strong>in</strong>fluenza outbreak, for example, could generate an unanticipated<br />

change <strong>in</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for budget resources. On the supply side, uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty could be<br />

driven by variation <strong>in</strong> the price or quality of desired goods <strong>and</strong> services. 2<br />

Third, resources that are not spent by the end of the year cannot be rolled over<br />

to produce value <strong>in</strong> subsequent periods. At the end of this section, we also analyze<br />

what happens when this constra<strong>in</strong>t is relaxed.<br />

4.2.1 The Basel<strong>in</strong>e Model<br />

Consider an annual model of budget<strong>in</strong>g where an <strong>organization</strong> chooses how to appor-<br />

tion budget authority, B, normalized to 1, over two six-month periods, denoted by<br />

t = {1, 2}, to maximize a Cobb-Douglas objective. Denote spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> each period by<br />

xt, <strong>and</strong> normalize its price to 1. To model decreas<strong>in</strong>g returns <strong>and</strong> uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, assume<br />

that the Cobb-Douglas elasticity parameters αt are stochastic i.i.d. draws from the<br />

2 As an example of supply side uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, dur<strong>in</strong>g the recent recession many agencies have experienced<br />

construction costs for Recovery Act projects that were below projections.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 159<br />

To summarize, decreas<strong>in</strong>g returns <strong>and</strong> uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty create an <strong>in</strong>centive for organi-<br />

zations to build up a ra<strong>in</strong>y day fund <strong>in</strong> the first period, spend<strong>in</strong>g less than half of their<br />

budget on average. At the end of the year, spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>and</strong> average quality is<br />

lower than <strong>in</strong> the earlier part of the year.<br />

It is worth emphasiz<strong>in</strong>g that this model illustrates two different channels through<br />

which end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g can be of lower quality. The first channel comes from<br />

the uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty about future needs <strong>and</strong> will lead <strong>organization</strong>s to engage <strong>in</strong> only<br />

high value projects early <strong>in</strong> the year <strong>and</strong> wait to undertake lower value projects once<br />

the full-year dem<strong>and</strong>s on resources are clearer. The second channel comes from the<br />

production-function rigidities motivated by the anecdotal evidence that contract<strong>in</strong>g<br />

officers become over-extended <strong>in</strong> the end-of-year rush to get money out the door.<br />

Either channel by itself would be enough to produce an empirical relationship <strong>in</strong><br />

which end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g is of lower value.<br />

4.2.2 Rollover Budget Authority<br />

The <strong>in</strong>efficiency from wasteful year-end spend<strong>in</strong>g raises the question of whether any-<br />

th<strong>in</strong>g can be done to reduce it. Reduc<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty would be helpful, but is <strong>in</strong>fea-<br />

sible <strong>in</strong> practice for many <strong>organization</strong>s due to the <strong>in</strong>herently unpredictable nature<br />

of some types of shocks. Another way to potentially <strong>in</strong>crease efficiency would be to<br />

allow <strong>organization</strong>s to roll over budget authority across fiscal years. Under such a<br />

system, budget<strong>in</strong>g would still occur on an annual basis, but rather than expir<strong>in</strong>g at<br />

year’s end, unused funds would be added to the newly granted budget authority <strong>in</strong><br />

the next year.<br />

The idea that budget authority should last for longer than one year is not new. As<br />

? has po<strong>in</strong>ted out, grant<strong>in</strong>g Congress the power to collect taxes, Article 1, Section 8<br />

of the U.S. Constitution gave Congress the power of taxation, “To raise <strong>and</strong> support<br />

armies, but no appropriation of money to that use shall be for longer term than two<br />

years.” Not only does this suggest that the Found<strong>in</strong>g Fathers though that two-year<br />

limits were reasonable <strong>in</strong> some <strong>in</strong>stances, but by fail<strong>in</strong>g to attach this clause to other<br />

forms of federal expenditure, they implied by omission that periods longer than two


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 162<br />

For many types of government spend<strong>in</strong>g, there is little potential for a spike <strong>in</strong><br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g at the end of the year. The 65 percent of spend<strong>in</strong>g that is made up of<br />

m<strong>and</strong>atory programs <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest on the debt is not subject to the tim<strong>in</strong>g limitations<br />

associated with annual appropriations. The 13 percent of spend<strong>in</strong>g that pays for<br />

compensation for federal employees is unlikely to exhibit an end-of-year surge s<strong>in</strong>ce<br />

new hires br<strong>in</strong>g ongo<strong>in</strong>g costs. This leaves procurement of goods <strong>and</strong> services from<br />

the private sector as the ma<strong>in</strong> category of government spend<strong>in</strong>g where an end-of-year<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g surge could potentially occur. We therefore focus our empirical work on the<br />

procurement of goods <strong>and</strong> services that accounted for $538 billion or 15.3 percent of<br />

government spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> 2009 (up from $165 billion dollars <strong>and</strong> 9.2 percent <strong>in</strong> 2000).<br />

It is worth not<strong>in</strong>g that even with<strong>in</strong> procurement spend<strong>in</strong>g, there are some cat-<br />

egories of spend<strong>in</strong>g for which it would be unlikely to observe an end-of-year spike.<br />

Some types of appropriated spend<strong>in</strong>g, such as military construction, come with longer<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g horizons to provide greater flexibility to agencies. Moreover, there are limits<br />

to what k<strong>in</strong>ds of purchases can be made at year end.<br />

In particular, Federal law provides that appropriations are available only to “meet<br />

the bona fide needs of the fiscal year for which they are appropriated.” Balances<br />

rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g at the end of the year cannot generally be used to prepay for the next<br />

year’s needs. A classic example of an improper obligation was an order for gasol<strong>in</strong>e<br />

placed 3 days before the end of the fiscal year to be delivered <strong>in</strong> monthly <strong>in</strong>stallments<br />

throughout the follow<strong>in</strong>g fiscal year (?). That said, when there is an ongo<strong>in</strong>g need<br />

<strong>and</strong> it is impossible to separate the purchase <strong>in</strong>to components performed <strong>in</strong> different<br />

fiscal years, it can be appropriate to enter <strong>in</strong>to a contract <strong>in</strong> one fiscal year even<br />

though a significant portion of the performance is <strong>in</strong> the subsequent fiscal year. In<br />

contrast, contracts that are readily severable generally may not cross fiscal years<br />

(unless specifically authorized by statute). 6<br />

6 Over the past two decades, Congress has significantly exp<strong>and</strong>ed multi-year contract<strong>in</strong>g authorities.<br />

For example, the General Services Adm<strong>in</strong>istration can enter <strong>in</strong>to leases for periods of up to 20<br />

years, <strong>and</strong> agencies can contract for services from utilities for periods of up to 10 years.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 163<br />

4.3.1 The Federal Procurement Data System<br />

Fall<strong>in</strong>g technology costs <strong>and</strong> the government transparency movement have comb<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

to produce an extraord<strong>in</strong>ary <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the amount of government data available on<br />

the web (??). As of October 2010, Data.gov had 2,936 U.S. federal executive branch<br />

datasets available. The Federal Fund<strong>in</strong>g Accountability <strong>and</strong> Transparency Act of<br />

2006, sponsored by Senators Coburn, Obama, Carper, <strong>and</strong> McCa<strong>in</strong>, required OMB<br />

to create a <strong>public</strong> website, show<strong>in</strong>g every federal award, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the name of the<br />

entity receiv<strong>in</strong>g the award <strong>and</strong> the amount of the award, among other <strong>in</strong>formation.<br />

USAspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov was launched <strong>in</strong> December 2007 <strong>and</strong> now conta<strong>in</strong>s data on federal<br />

contracts, grants, direct payments, <strong>and</strong> loans.<br />

The data currently available on USAspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov <strong>in</strong>clude the full Federal Procure-<br />

ment Data System (FPDS) from 2000 through 2009. FPDS is the data system that<br />

tracks all federal contracts. Every new contract awarded as well as every follow-on<br />

contract<strong>in</strong>g action such as a contract renewal or modification results <strong>in</strong> an observation<br />

<strong>in</strong> FPDS. Up to 176 pieces of <strong>in</strong>formation are available for each contract <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g<br />

dollar value, a four digit code describ<strong>in</strong>g the product or service be<strong>in</strong>g purchased, the<br />

component of the agency mak<strong>in</strong>g the purchase, the identity of the provider, the type<br />

of contract be<strong>in</strong>g used (fixed price, cost-type, time <strong>and</strong> materials, etc.), <strong>and</strong> the type<br />

of bidd<strong>in</strong>g mechanism used. While FPDS was orig<strong>in</strong>ally created <strong>in</strong> 1978, agency re-<br />

port<strong>in</strong>g was <strong>in</strong>complete for many years, <strong>and</strong> we are told that it would be difficult to<br />

assemble comprehensive data for years before 2000. Moreover, while FPDS is thought<br />

to conta<strong>in</strong> all government contracts from 2000 on, data quality for many fields was<br />

uneven before the 2003 FPDS modernization. Therefore, for most of the FPDS-based<br />

analyses <strong>in</strong> this paper, we limit ourselves to data from fiscal years 2004 through 2009. 7<br />

Table 4.1 shows selected characteristics of the FPDS 2004 to 2009 sample. There<br />

were 14.6 million contracts dur<strong>in</strong>g this period or an average of 2.4 million a year.<br />

The distribution of contract size is highly skewed. N<strong>in</strong>ety-five percent of contracts<br />

were for dollar amounts below $100,000, while 78 percent of contract spend<strong>in</strong>g is<br />

7 FPDS excludes classified contracts. Data are made available <strong>in</strong> FPDS soon after an award,<br />

except dur<strong>in</strong>g wartime the Department of Defense is permitted a 90 day delay to m<strong>in</strong>imize the<br />

potential for disclosure of mission critical <strong>in</strong>formation.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 164<br />

accounted for by contracts of more than $1 million. Seventy percent of contract<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g is by the Department of Defense. The Department of Energy <strong>and</strong> NASA,<br />

which rely on contractors to run large labs <strong>and</strong> production facilities, <strong>and</strong> the General<br />

Services Adm<strong>in</strong>istration, which enters <strong>in</strong>to government-wide contracts <strong>and</strong> contracts<br />

on behalf of other agencies, are the next largest agencies <strong>in</strong> terms of spend<strong>in</strong>g on<br />

contracts. Twenty-n<strong>in</strong>e percent of contracts were non-competitive, 20 percent were<br />

competitive but received only a s<strong>in</strong>gle bid, <strong>and</strong> 51 percent received more than 1 bid.<br />

Sixty-five percent were fixed price, 30 percent were cost-reimbursement, <strong>and</strong> 6 percent<br />

were on a time <strong>and</strong> materials or labor hours basis.<br />

4.3.2 The With<strong>in</strong>-Year Pattern of Government Procurement<br />

Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Figure 4.1 shows contract spend<strong>in</strong>g by week, pool<strong>in</strong>g data from 2004 through 2009.<br />

There is a clear spike <strong>in</strong> spend<strong>in</strong>g at the end of the year with 16.5 percent of all<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g occurr<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the last month of the year <strong>and</strong> 8.7 percent occurr<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the<br />

last week. The bottom panel shows that when measured by the number of contracts<br />

rather than the dollar value, there is also clear evidence of an end-of-the-year spike,<br />

with 12.0 percent occurr<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the last month <strong>and</strong> 5.6 percent occurr<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the last<br />

week.<br />

Table 4.1 shows that the end of the year spend<strong>in</strong>g surge occurs <strong>in</strong> all major<br />

government agencies. If spend<strong>in</strong>g were distributed uniformly throughout the year,<br />

we would expect to see 1.9 percent <strong>in</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al week of the year. The lowest agency<br />

percentage is 3.6 percent.<br />

Table 4.3 shows the percent of spend<strong>in</strong>g on different types of goods <strong>and</strong> services<br />

that occurs at the end of the year. The table shows some of the largest spend-<br />

<strong>in</strong>g categories along with some selected smaller categories that are very similar to<br />

the large categories. Construction-related goods <strong>and</strong> services, furnish<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> office<br />

equipment, <strong>and</strong> I.T. services <strong>and</strong> equipment all have end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g rates that<br />

are significantly higher than the average. These categories of spend<strong>in</strong>g often represent<br />

areas where there is significant flexibility about tim<strong>in</strong>g for perform<strong>in</strong>g ma<strong>in</strong>tenance


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 165<br />

or upgrad<strong>in</strong>g facilities <strong>and</strong> equipment, <strong>and</strong> which, because they represent on-go<strong>in</strong>g<br />

needs, have a reasonable chance of satisfy<strong>in</strong>g the bona fide needs requirement even if<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g happens at the end of the year.<br />

The categories of spend<strong>in</strong>g under the “Services” head<strong>in</strong>g have end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

rates that are near the average. For these k<strong>in</strong>ds of services it will often be difficult to<br />

meet the bona fide needs requirements unless the services are <strong>in</strong>separable from larger<br />

purchases, the services are necessary to provide cont<strong>in</strong>uity <strong>in</strong>to the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the<br />

next fiscal year, or the services are covered by special multiyear contract<strong>in</strong>g authori-<br />

ties. Thus it is not surpris<strong>in</strong>g that their rate of end of year spend<strong>in</strong>g is lower than that<br />

for construction, for example. There are two categories of spend<strong>in</strong>g where there is<br />

very little year-end surge. The first is ongo<strong>in</strong>g expenses such as fuels where attempts<br />

to spend at the end of the year would represent a blatant violation of prohibitions<br />

aga<strong>in</strong>st pay<strong>in</strong>g for the follow<strong>in</strong>g year’s expenses with current year appropriations.<br />

The second is military weapons systems where because of long plann<strong>in</strong>g horizons <strong>and</strong><br />

the flexibility provided by special appropriations authorities, one would not expect<br />

to see a concentration of spend<strong>in</strong>g at the end of the year.<br />

Figure 4.1 also shows a spike <strong>in</strong> spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the first week of the year, along with<br />

smaller spikes at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of each quarter. The spend<strong>in</strong>g patterns for these<br />

beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of period contracts are very different from those at the end of the year.<br />

Appendix Table 4.9 shows that leases <strong>and</strong> service contracts are responsible for most<br />

of the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g-of-period spikes.<br />

4.3.3 The Impact of Appropriations Tim<strong>in</strong>g on the With<strong>in</strong>-<br />

Year Pattern of Government Procurement Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

It is the exception rather than the rule for Congress to pass annual appropriations<br />

bills before the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the fiscal year. Over the 10 years from 2000 to 2009, the<br />

full annual appropriations process was never completed on time. Although defense<br />

appropriations bills were enacted before the start of the fiscal year 4 times, <strong>in</strong> 8 of<br />

the ten years, appropriations for all or nearly all of the civilian agencies were enacted<br />

<strong>in</strong> a s<strong>in</strong>gle consolidated appropriations act well after the start of the fiscal year.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 166<br />

Analysts have attributed some of the challenges fac<strong>in</strong>g federal acquisition to the<br />

tard<strong>in</strong>ess of the appropriations process, s<strong>in</strong>ce the delays <strong>in</strong>troduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>and</strong><br />

compress the time available to plan <strong>and</strong> implement a successful acquisition strategy<br />

(?). In this subsection we analyze the relationship between the tim<strong>in</strong>g of the annual<br />

appropriations acts <strong>and</strong> the with<strong>in</strong>-year pattern of government contract spend<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

For this analysis, we use the full 2000 to 2009 FPDS data, even though the data prior<br />

to 2004 are of lower quality. In particular, <strong>in</strong> these earlier years it appears that for<br />

some agencies, contracts are all assigned dates <strong>in</strong> the middle of the month <strong>and</strong> the<br />

with<strong>in</strong>-month weekly pattern is therefore not fully available.<br />

Figure 4.2 shows results from regress<strong>in</strong>g measures of end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g on the<br />

tim<strong>in</strong>g of annual appropriations. This analysis has two data po<strong>in</strong>ts for each year,<br />

one represent<strong>in</strong>g defense spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> the other represent<strong>in</strong>g non-defense spend<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

For each observation we measure the share of annual contract spend<strong>in</strong>g occurr<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong><br />

the last quarter, month, <strong>and</strong> week of the year <strong>and</strong> the “weeks late” of the enactment<br />

of annual appropriations legislation (enactment is def<strong>in</strong>ed by the date the President<br />

signs the legislation). “Weeks late” measures time relative to October 1 <strong>and</strong> takes on<br />

negative values when appropriations were enacted prior to the start of the fiscal year.<br />

For defense spend<strong>in</strong>g, “weeks late” measures the date that the defense appropriations<br />

bill was enacted. For non-defense spend<strong>in</strong>g the date is assigned from the date of<br />

the consolidated appropriations act, or, <strong>in</strong> the case of the two years <strong>in</strong> which there<br />

was not a consolidated act, a date that is the midpo<strong>in</strong>t of the <strong>in</strong>dividual non-defense<br />

appropriations acts. 8<br />

There is a clear pattern <strong>in</strong> the data <strong>in</strong> which later appropriation dates result<br />

<strong>in</strong> a greater fraction of end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g. In the plots, we show the separate<br />

slopes of the defense <strong>and</strong> non-defense observations. Defense spend<strong>in</strong>g tends to be<br />

appropriated earlier <strong>and</strong> to have less end of year spend<strong>in</strong>g, but the slopes for the two<br />

types of spend<strong>in</strong>g are similar. The labels show the regression coefficients, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the coefficients from a pooled regression <strong>in</strong> which defense <strong>and</strong> non-defense spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

8 We aggregate all non-defense spend<strong>in</strong>g because it facilitates communication of the pattern of<br />

results while captur<strong>in</strong>g nearly all of the available variation. We have also run analysis <strong>in</strong> which we<br />

assign each non-defense agency the date of its <strong>in</strong>dividual appropriations act <strong>and</strong> obta<strong>in</strong> very similar<br />

results.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 167<br />

have different <strong>in</strong>tercepts but are constra<strong>in</strong>ed to have the same slope. The estimates<br />

show that a delay of ten weeks, roughly the average over this time period, raises the<br />

share of spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the last quarter by 2 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts from a base of about<br />

27 percent. A ten-week delay raises the share of spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the last month by 1<br />

percentage po<strong>in</strong>t, from a base of about 15 percent. Both coefficients are statistically<br />

significant at the 1 percent level. As we mentioned above, we do not have reliable<br />

with<strong>in</strong>-month data on tim<strong>in</strong>g for the years before 2004, so we exclude years before<br />

2004 for the analysis of spend<strong>in</strong>g dur<strong>in</strong>g the last week of the year. The estimates<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicate that a 10 week delay raises the share of spend<strong>in</strong>g by 1 percentage po<strong>in</strong>t on<br />

a base of 9 percent. Due to the smaller sample, the estimate is less precise, with a<br />

p-value of .07.<br />

Overall, the analysis <strong>in</strong> this section shows that the end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g surge<br />

is alive <strong>and</strong> well, thirty years after Congress <strong>and</strong> GAO focused significant attention<br />

on the problem <strong>and</strong> despite reforms designed to limit it. Moreover, claims that late<br />

appropriations <strong>in</strong>crease the end-of-year volume of contract<strong>in</strong>g activity are accurate,<br />

suggest<strong>in</strong>g that late appropriations may be exacerbat<strong>in</strong>g the already adverse effects<br />

of hav<strong>in</strong>g an acquisition workforce operat<strong>in</strong>g beyond capacity at the end of the year.<br />

A surge <strong>in</strong> end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g does not necessarily imply bad outcomes. Agency<br />

acquisition staff can plan ahead for the possibility that extra funds will be available.<br />

Indeed, for large contracts weeks <strong>and</strong> even months of lead time are generally necessary.<br />

The next section of the paper therefore analyzes the relative quality of end-of-year<br />

contract spend<strong>in</strong>g to explore whether there are any adverse effects of the end-of-year<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g surge.<br />

4.4 Is End of Year Spend<strong>in</strong>g of Lower Quality?<br />

Our model predicts that end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g will be of lower quality both because<br />

agencies will spend money at the end of the year on low value projects <strong>and</strong> because<br />

the <strong>in</strong>creased volume of contract<strong>in</strong>g at the end of the year will lead to less effective<br />

management of those acquisitions. As the discussion <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>troduction <strong>in</strong>dicated,<br />

it has been challeng<strong>in</strong>g historically to study contract quality because of the limited


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 168<br />

availability of data. In this section of the paper, we use a new dataset that <strong>in</strong>cludes<br />

quality <strong>in</strong>formation on 686 of the most important federal I.T. procurements to study<br />

whether end-of-the year procurements are of lower quality.<br />

4.4.1 I.T. Dashboard<br />

Our data come from the federal I.T. Dashboard (www.itdashboard.gov) which tracks<br />

the performance of the most important federal I.T. projects. The I.T. Dashboard<br />

came onl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> beta form <strong>in</strong> June, 2009 <strong>and</strong> provides the <strong>public</strong> with measures of<br />

the overall performance of major I.T. projects. Like the USAspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov data dis-<br />

cussed earlier, the I.T. Dashboard is part of the trend toward “open government”<br />

<strong>and</strong> part of a shift <strong>in</strong> federal management philosophy toward monitor<strong>in</strong>g performance<br />

trends rather than tak<strong>in</strong>g static snapshots of performance <strong>and</strong> of mak<strong>in</strong>g the trends<br />

<strong>public</strong> both for the sake of transparency <strong>and</strong> to motivate agencies to achieve high<br />

performance (?). 9<br />

Along with provid<strong>in</strong>g credible performance data for a portion of contract spend<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

study<strong>in</strong>g federal I.T. projects has two other advantages. The first is the ubiquity of<br />

I.T. spend<strong>in</strong>g. Major <strong>in</strong>formation technology projects are carried out by nearly all<br />

components of the U.S. federal government. Compared to an analysis of, say, the<br />

purchase of military or medical equipment, an analysis of I.T. spend<strong>in</strong>g sh<strong>in</strong>es a much<br />

broader light on the work<strong>in</strong>gs of government, allow<strong>in</strong>g us to test our hypotheses across<br />

agencies with a wide range of missions <strong>and</strong> <strong>organization</strong>al cultures.<br />

The second advantage is that federal I.T. spend<strong>in</strong>g is an important <strong>and</strong> grow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

federal activity. Federal I.T. expenditure was $81.9 billion <strong>in</strong> 2010, <strong>and</strong> has been grow-<br />

<strong>in</strong>g at an <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted rate of 3.8 percent over the past 5 years. 10 . Moreover,<br />

these expenditure levels do not account for the social surplus from these projects.<br />

9 The legislative foundation for the I.T. Dashboard was laid by the Cl<strong>in</strong>ger-Cohen Act of 1996,<br />

which established Chief Information Officers at 27 major federal agencies <strong>and</strong> called on them to<br />

“monitor the performance of the <strong>in</strong>formation technology programs of the agency, [<strong>and</strong>] evaluate<br />

the performance of those programs on the basis of applicable performance measurements.” The<br />

E-Government Act of 2002 built upon this by requir<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>public</strong> display of these data.<br />

10 Analytical Perspectives: Budget of the U.S. Government, 2010


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 169<br />

It is reasonable to th<strong>in</strong>k that <strong>in</strong>formation systems used to monitor terrorist activi-<br />

ties, adm<strong>in</strong>ister Social Security payments, <strong>and</strong> coord<strong>in</strong>ate the health care of military<br />

veterans could have welfare impacts that far exceed their dollar costs.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, it should be noted that while we are duly cautious about external validly,<br />

the widespread nature of I.T. <strong>in</strong>vestment across all types of <strong>organization</strong>s, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g<br />

private sector ones, makes a study of I.T. purchases more broadly relevant than would<br />

be certa<strong>in</strong> other categories of spend<strong>in</strong>g where the federal government may be the only<br />

purchaser. Not only do non-federal <strong>organization</strong>s buy similar products under similar<br />

budget structures, but they often purchase these products from the same firms that<br />

sell to U.S. federal agencies. These firms know the end-of-year budget<strong>in</strong>g game, <strong>and</strong> if<br />

they play it at the U.S. federal level, there may be reason to believe that they operate<br />

similarly elsewhere. 11<br />

4.4.2 Data <strong>and</strong> Summary Statistics<br />

The I.T. Dashboard displays <strong>in</strong>formation on major, ongo<strong>in</strong>g projects made by 27 of<br />

the largest agencies of the federal government. The <strong>in</strong>formation is gleaned from the<br />

Exhibit 53 <strong>and</strong> Exhibit 300 forms that agencies are required to submit to the Office<br />

of Management <strong>and</strong> Budget <strong>and</strong> is constantly updated on the Dashboard website,<br />

allow<strong>in</strong>g users to view <strong>and</strong> conduct simple analysis of the data. The data we use was<br />

downloaded <strong>in</strong> March, 2010 at which time there were 761 projects be<strong>in</strong>g tracked.<br />

For the analysis, we drop the 73 observations that are miss<strong>in</strong>g the quality mea-<br />

sures, date of award, or cost variables. We also drop two enormous projects because<br />

their size would cause them to dom<strong>in</strong>ate all of the weighted regression results <strong>and</strong><br />

because they are too high-profile to be <strong>in</strong>dicative of normal budget<strong>in</strong>g practices. 12<br />

This leaves us with a basel<strong>in</strong>e sample of 686 projects <strong>and</strong> $130 billion <strong>in</strong> planned<br />

total spend<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

11 See ? for a discussion of the <strong>in</strong>centives fac<strong>in</strong>g government contractors.<br />

12 These projects are a $45.5 billion project at the Department of Defense <strong>and</strong> a $19.5 billion<br />

project at the Department of Homel<strong>and</strong> Security; the next largest project is $3.9 billion <strong>and</strong> the<br />

average of the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g observations is $219 million. Because the dropped observations have above<br />

average overall rat<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> are not from the last week of the year, omitt<strong>in</strong>g the observations works<br />

aga<strong>in</strong>st us f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g the effect predicted my our model.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 170<br />

Table 4.4 shows the year of orig<strong>in</strong>ation of these projects <strong>and</strong> the agencies at which<br />

they occurred. Almost two-thirds of these projects (64.6 percent) <strong>and</strong> half of the<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g (50.3 percent) orig<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> 2005 or later, although there are some ongo<strong>in</strong>g<br />

projects that orig<strong>in</strong>ated more than 20 years ago. 13 The projects are distributed<br />

fairly broadly across agencies. Although the Department of Defense, Department of<br />

Transportation, <strong>and</strong> Department of Veteran’s Affairs have higher levels of spend<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

the vast majority of the agencies have at least 10 projects (21 of 27) <strong>and</strong> at least $1<br />

billion <strong>in</strong> aggregate spend<strong>in</strong>g (20 of 27).<br />

The ma<strong>in</strong> performance measure tracked on the I.T. dashboard is the overall rat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

for the project. The canonical approach to track<strong>in</strong>g acquisitions is to measure cost,<br />

schedule, <strong>and</strong> performance. The overall rat<strong>in</strong>g therefore comb<strong>in</strong>es three sub<strong>in</strong>dexes.<br />

The cost rat<strong>in</strong>g sub<strong>in</strong>dex is based on the absolute percent deviation between the<br />

planned <strong>and</strong> actual cost of the project. Projects that are on average with<strong>in</strong> 5 percent<br />

of the scheduled cost receive a score of 10, projects that are with<strong>in</strong> 5 percent to 10<br />

percent on average receive a score of 9, <strong>and</strong> so on down to zero. Because the symmetric<br />

treatment of under <strong>and</strong> over-cost projects is somewhat unnatural, <strong>in</strong> our analysis we<br />

also construct an alternative <strong>in</strong>dex, “cost overrun” which gives under-cost projects<br />

the highest scores <strong>and</strong> over-cost projects the lowest. In this <strong>in</strong>dex, projects that are<br />

at least 45 percent under-cost receive a score of 10, projects that are 35 percent to 45<br />

percent under-cost receive a score of 9, <strong>and</strong> so on.<br />

The schedule rat<strong>in</strong>g sub<strong>in</strong>dex is based on the average tard<strong>in</strong>ess of the project<br />

across milestones. Projects that are no more than 30 days overdue on average receive<br />

a score of 10, projects that are no more than 90 days overdue on average receive a<br />

score of 5, <strong>and</strong> projects that are more than 90 days overdue on average receive a score<br />

of 0.<br />

The third sub<strong>in</strong>dex is a subjective CIO evaluation score, designed to <strong>in</strong>corporate<br />

an assessment of contract performance. The rat<strong>in</strong>g is <strong>in</strong>tended to reflect the CIO’s<br />

“assessment of the risk of the <strong>in</strong>vestment’s ability to accomplish its goals,” with<br />

the CIO <strong>in</strong>structed to “consult appropriate stakeholders <strong>in</strong> mak<strong>in</strong>g their evaluation,<br />

13 We address sample selection issues <strong>in</strong> the sensitivity section below.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 172<br />

To classify year-end projects, we use the date the first contract of the projects was<br />

signed, creat<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>dicator variable for projects that orig<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> the last seven<br />

days of September, the end of the fiscal year. Most I.T. projects are comprised of a<br />

series of contracts that are renewed <strong>and</strong> altered as milestones are met <strong>and</strong> the nature<br />

of the project evolves. We th<strong>in</strong>k that us<strong>in</strong>g the date the first contract was signed<br />

to classify the start date of the project is the best approach as the key structure of<br />

the project is most likely determ<strong>in</strong>ed at its onset. While future contract awards may<br />

affect the quality of the project, we only observe outcomes at the project level. We<br />

view any potential measurement error from our approach as <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g downward<br />

bias <strong>in</strong> our coefficient of <strong>in</strong>terest as contracts <strong>in</strong>itially awarded before the last week<br />

of the year may be contam<strong>in</strong>ated by modifications made <strong>in</strong> the last week of a later<br />

year <strong>and</strong> contracts <strong>in</strong>itially awarded at the rush of year’s end may be rectified at a<br />

later po<strong>in</strong>t.<br />

Figure 4.3 shows the weekly pattern of spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the I.T. Dashboard sample.<br />

As <strong>in</strong> the broader FPDS sample, there is a spike <strong>in</strong> spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the 52nd week of the<br />

year. Spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> the number of projects <strong>in</strong> the last week <strong>in</strong>crease to 7.2 <strong>and</strong> 8.3<br />

times their rest-of-year weekly averages respectively. Alternatively put, while only<br />

account<strong>in</strong>g for 1.9 percent of the days of the year, the last week accounts for 12.3<br />

percent of spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> 14.0 percent of the number of projects. Activity is tilted<br />

even more strongly towards the last week if the sample of projects is restricted to<br />

the 65.1 percent of contracts that are for less than $100 million. Given the longer<br />

plann<strong>in</strong>g horizon for larger acquisitions, it is not surpris<strong>in</strong>g that we see more of a<br />

year-end spike for the smaller contracts. 17<br />

4.4.3 The Relative Quality of Year-End I.T. Contracts<br />

Figure 4.4 shows the distributions of the overall rat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex for last-week-of-the-year<br />

projects <strong>and</strong> projects from the rest of the year. In these histograms, the rat<strong>in</strong>gs on<br />

the 0 to 10 scale are b<strong>in</strong>ned <strong>in</strong>to 5 categories with the lowest category represent<strong>in</strong>g<br />

overall rat<strong>in</strong>gs less than 2, the second lowest represent<strong>in</strong>g overall rat<strong>in</strong>gs between 2<br />

17 As <strong>in</strong> the broader FPDS sample, the end of year spike <strong>in</strong> the I.T. data is a broad phenomenon,<br />

not limited to a few agencies.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 174<br />

Recall that odds ratios capture the proportional change <strong>in</strong> the odds of a higher cat-<br />

egorical value associated with a unit <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the dependent variable, so that an<br />

odds ratio of 1/2 <strong>in</strong>dicates that the odds of a higher categorical value are 50 percent<br />

lower, or reciprocally that the odds of a lower categorical variable are 2 times as great.<br />

The results <strong>in</strong> this table are weighted by <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted spend<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

The first column of the table shows the impact of a last week contract on the<br />

rat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a regression with no covariates. Columns 2 through 4 sequentially add <strong>in</strong><br />

fixed effects for year, agency, <strong>and</strong> project characteristics. In all of the specifications,<br />

the odds ratios are well below one—rang<strong>in</strong>g from 0.18 to 0.46—imply<strong>in</strong>g that last week<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g is of significantly lower quality than spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the rest of the year (the<br />

p-values are less than 0.01 <strong>in</strong> all specifications). The estimates imply that spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

that orig<strong>in</strong>ates <strong>in</strong> the last week of the fiscal year has 2.2 to 5.6 times higher odds of<br />

hav<strong>in</strong>g a lower quality score.<br />

4.4.4 Sensitivity Analysis<br />

This subsection explores the robustness of the basic estimates. It shows how the<br />

results vary with different treatment of large contracts, with different functional form<br />

assumptions, <strong>and</strong> when selection <strong>in</strong>to the sample is modeled.<br />

Figure 4.4 showed that the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g that year end projects are of lower quality was<br />

more pronounced <strong>in</strong> the dollar weighted analysis than <strong>in</strong> the unweighted analysis,<br />

suggest<strong>in</strong>g that a few large poor perform<strong>in</strong>g contracts may be heavily affect<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

results. The first four columns of Table 4.7 analyze this issue. The first two columns<br />

split the sample at the median contract size of $62 million. In the sample of smaller<br />

contracts, the coefficient of 0.60 is substantially below one but is less precisely es-<br />

timated (p-value of 0.17). The po<strong>in</strong>t estimate <strong>in</strong> column (3) from an unweighted<br />

regression is quite similar to the estimate <strong>in</strong> column (1) for the smaller contracts,<br />

but with added precision from doubl<strong>in</strong>g the sample size by <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the full sam-<br />

ple (p-value of .02). Results <strong>in</strong> which we W<strong>in</strong>sorize the weights, assign<strong>in</strong>g a weight<br />

of $1 billion to the 4 percent of projects that are larger than $1 billion, are about<br />

half way between the full sample weighted <strong>and</strong> unweighted results (p-value less than


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 175<br />

0.01). Overall, it is clear that the pattern of lower rat<strong>in</strong>g for end of year contracts is<br />

a broad phenomenon. It is also clear that the sample conta<strong>in</strong>s several very large low<br />

rated projects that were orig<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> the last week of the year—possibly provid<strong>in</strong>g<br />

evidence that it is particularly risky to rush very large contracts out the door as the<br />

fiscal year deadl<strong>in</strong>e approaches.<br />

Column (5) of Table 4.4 shows results from an ord<strong>in</strong>ary least squares (OLS) model<br />

<strong>in</strong> which the raw overall rat<strong>in</strong>g is regressed on an <strong>in</strong>dicator for the contract orig<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong> the last week of the year <strong>and</strong> on controls. The regression coefficient of -1.00 shows<br />

that I.T. spend<strong>in</strong>g contracted <strong>in</strong> the last week of the year receives rat<strong>in</strong>gs that are<br />

on average a full po<strong>in</strong>t lower on the 0 to 10 rat<strong>in</strong>g scale. This estimate also confirms<br />

that the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g of lower quality year end spend<strong>in</strong>g is not limited to the ordered logit<br />

functional form.<br />

An important feature of our sample is that it reflects only active I.T. projects.<br />

Projects that have already been completed or projects that were term<strong>in</strong>ated without<br />

reach<strong>in</strong>g completion are not <strong>in</strong> our sample. Unfortunately, because the I.T. dashboard<br />

<strong>and</strong> the CIO rat<strong>in</strong>gs are br<strong>and</strong> new, it is not possible to acquire rat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

on the major I.T. projects that are no longer ongo<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Ideally, one would want a sample of all major I.T. projects that orig<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> a<br />

particular period <strong>in</strong> time. The bias <strong>in</strong>troduced by the way <strong>in</strong> which our sample was<br />

constructed most likely leads us to underestimate the end-of-year-effect. In particular,<br />

very bad contracts begun <strong>in</strong> the last week of the year are likely to be canceled <strong>and</strong><br />

would not appear <strong>in</strong> our data set. Similarly, very well executed contracts from earlier<br />

<strong>in</strong> the year are likely to be completed ahead of schedule <strong>and</strong> also not appear <strong>in</strong> our<br />

data set. Thus, our estimates likely understate the gap <strong>in</strong> quality that we would f<strong>in</strong>d<br />

if we could compare all contracts from the last week of the year with all contracts<br />

from the rest of the year.<br />

To explore the extent of bias that a selection mechanism like the one just described<br />

might <strong>in</strong>troduce <strong>in</strong>to our estimates, we assembled a data set of all 3,859 major I.T.<br />

projects that orig<strong>in</strong>ated between 2002 <strong>and</strong> 2010. We were able to assemble this data<br />

set us<strong>in</strong>g the annual Exhibit 53 reports that allow the Office of Management <strong>and</strong><br />

Budget to track I.T. projects across the major federal agencies. These data show that


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 176<br />

more recently orig<strong>in</strong>ated projects are significantly more likely to be <strong>in</strong> our sample.<br />

Our sample conta<strong>in</strong>s 85 percent of the total spend<strong>in</strong>g on projects that orig<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong><br />

2007 or later <strong>and</strong> only 28 percent of the spend<strong>in</strong>g on projects that orig<strong>in</strong>ated before<br />

this date.<br />

A simple way to assess whether there is selection is to estimate the model on<br />

samples split <strong>in</strong>to earlier <strong>and</strong> later years. A difference <strong>in</strong> the coefficient of <strong>in</strong>terest<br />

across samples, given the assumption that there is no time trend <strong>in</strong> the effect, would<br />

be <strong>in</strong>dicative of selection bias. Given this assumption, however, we can estimate the<br />

parameter of <strong>in</strong>terest exactly by us<strong>in</strong>g the date of project orig<strong>in</strong>ation to identify a<br />

selection correction term. Column (6) implements this strategy, show<strong>in</strong>g estimates<br />

from a st<strong>and</strong>ard Heckman selection model where the year or orig<strong>in</strong>ation is excluded<br />

from the second stage. The results show a larger effect than the correspond<strong>in</strong>g OLS<br />

estimate, but the lack of precession means that we cannot rule out that the effects<br />

are the same. 19 The negative coefficient on the selection term, although statistically<br />

<strong>in</strong>dist<strong>in</strong>guishable from zero, suggests that lower quality projects are on net more likely<br />

to rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> the sample over time.<br />

4.4.5 Why Are Year End Contracts of Lower Quality?<br />

The results from the I.T. dashboard show that, consistent with the predictions of our<br />

model, year end spend<strong>in</strong>g is of lower quality than spend<strong>in</strong>g obligated earlier <strong>in</strong> the<br />

year. 20 Our model posited two channels: agencies may save low priority projects for<br />

the end of the year <strong>and</strong> undertake them only if they have no better uses for the funds,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the high volume of contract<strong>in</strong>g activity at the end of the year might allow for<br />

less management attention per project.<br />

19 Consistent with this f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g, OLS estimates on a sample split <strong>in</strong> 2007 show a larger po<strong>in</strong>t estimate<br />

<strong>in</strong> the later years, but we cannot reject the hypothesis that the coefficients are the same.<br />

20 In addition to the last week of the year results described above, we have also exam<strong>in</strong>ed last<br />

month of the year spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d that spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the balance of the last month of the year is of<br />

moderately lower quality than that <strong>in</strong> the first 11 months of the year. We have also exam<strong>in</strong>ed the<br />

quality of first week of the year spend<strong>in</strong>g (which also spikes). The po<strong>in</strong>t estimate for the first week<br />

of the year suggests somewhat higher spend<strong>in</strong>g quality, but the odds ratio difference from 1.0 is not<br />

statistically significant.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 177<br />

There is also a third possible mechanism. 21 Some program managers or contract<strong>in</strong>g<br />

officers may be <strong>in</strong>cl<strong>in</strong>ed toward procrast<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>and</strong> these same employees may be ones<br />

who do a worse job of plann<strong>in</strong>g for, writ<strong>in</strong>g, or manag<strong>in</strong>g contracts. Thus, we may<br />

see a surge of low quality contracts at the end of the year because that is when the<br />

least effective acquisition professionals get their contracts out the door. This third<br />

mechanism could have different policy implications from the first two because allow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

agencies to roll over funds would not necessarily improve outcomes—the least effective<br />

acquisition professionals would simply issue their contracts at a different time of year.<br />

One way to evaluate this procrast<strong>in</strong>ation hypothesis would be to exam<strong>in</strong>e the with<strong>in</strong>-<br />

year calendar distribution of other contracts issued by the contract<strong>in</strong>g officers who<br />

issued last week contracts <strong>in</strong> our I.T. Dashboard sample to see if they appear to be<br />

procrast<strong>in</strong>ators who consistently complete their contracts late <strong>in</strong> the year. While we<br />

can identify the contract<strong>in</strong>g officers responsible for a contract <strong>in</strong> both the dashboard<br />

sample <strong>and</strong> the FPDS sample, we cannot currently l<strong>in</strong>k the two samples, though we<br />

believe we ultimately will be able to do so.<br />

Another way to explore the possible mechanisms beh<strong>in</strong>d the poor outcomes for<br />

end-of-year contracts is to exam<strong>in</strong>e the subcomponents of the overall rat<strong>in</strong>g to see<br />

which sub<strong>in</strong>dices are responsible for the result. Appendix Table 4.10 repeats our ma<strong>in</strong><br />

ordered logit analysis with each sub<strong>in</strong>dex as the dependent variable. The results show<br />

clearly that it is the evaluation by the agency CIO that is responsible for the ma<strong>in</strong><br />

f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g. Neither the cost rat<strong>in</strong>g nor the schedule rat<strong>in</strong>g has an odds ratio that is<br />

significantly different from 1. The CIO evaluation shows that the odds of hav<strong>in</strong>g a<br />

higher rat<strong>in</strong>g are one-sixth as high for last-week-of-the-year contracts. The coefficient<br />

<strong>in</strong> the CIO regression is <strong>in</strong>sensitive to add<strong>in</strong>g the cost rat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> schedul<strong>in</strong>g rat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>to the regression, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that it is <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> the CIO rat<strong>in</strong>g that is not<br />

<strong>in</strong>corporated <strong>in</strong> the other rat<strong>in</strong>g that is responsible for the result. This f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g is not<br />

all that surpris<strong>in</strong>g. As we mentioned above, the I.T. dashboard explicitly places more<br />

faith <strong>in</strong> the CIO’s assessment than <strong>in</strong> the other components by allow<strong>in</strong>g the CIO<br />

assessment to override the other components if it is lower than the other components.<br />

Moreover, the ability to reset milestone targets makes it difficult to assess the cost<br />

21 We thank Steve Kelman for suggest<strong>in</strong>g this third mechanism.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 178<br />

<strong>and</strong> schedule rat<strong>in</strong>gs. But while not surpris<strong>in</strong>g, the fact that it is the CIO evaluation<br />

that is driv<strong>in</strong>g the result means that we cannot learn much about the mechanism<br />

from the sub<strong>in</strong>dices, s<strong>in</strong>ce the CIO evaluation <strong>in</strong> a comprehensive measure of the I.T.<br />

project’s performance.<br />

Another way to explore possible mechanisms is to exam<strong>in</strong>e whether other ob-<br />

servable features of end-of-year contracts are different from those earlier <strong>in</strong> the year.<br />

Specifically, we exam<strong>in</strong>e whether features that policymakers often def<strong>in</strong>e as high risk—<br />

such as lack of competitive bidd<strong>in</strong>g or use of cost-reimbursement rather than fixed<br />

cost pric<strong>in</strong>g—are more prevalent <strong>in</strong> end of year contracts. For this analysis we return<br />

to the FPDS sample of all contracts from 2004 to 2009. To facilitate the analysis,<br />

we aggregate the 14.6 million observations up to the level of the covariates. We then<br />

estimate l<strong>in</strong>ear probability models with <strong>in</strong>dicators for contract characteristics (e.g.,<br />

a non-competitively sourced <strong>in</strong>dicator) as the dependent variable on an <strong>in</strong>dicator<br />

for last week of the fiscal year <strong>and</strong> controls. The regressions are weighted by total<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> each cell.<br />

The first three columns of Appendix Table 4.11 exam<strong>in</strong>e shifts <strong>in</strong> the degree of<br />

competitive sourc<strong>in</strong>g at the end of the year. The use of non-competitive contracts<br />

shows little change. However, contracts that are competitively sourced are signifi-<br />

cantly more likely to receive only one bid perhaps because the end of year rush leaves<br />

less time to allow bidd<strong>in</strong>g to take place. The estimates <strong>in</strong>dicate that there is almost<br />

a 10 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the percent of contracts receiv<strong>in</strong>g only a s<strong>in</strong>gle bid—a 1.7<br />

percentage po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>crease one a base of 20 percent. On net, then, there is a modest<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> “risky” non-competitive <strong>and</strong> one bid contracts at the end of the year.<br />

Column (3) shows that spend<strong>in</strong>g on contracts that are either non-competitive or one<br />

bid contract <strong>in</strong>creases by 1 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts on a base of 49 percent <strong>in</strong> the last week<br />

of the year.<br />

The second three columns <strong>in</strong>vestigate the type of contract used. Contracts that<br />

provide for cost reimbursement rather than specify<strong>in</strong>g a fixed price are often seen as<br />

high risk because they have significant potential for cost overruns. Time <strong>and</strong> material<br />

or labor hours (T&M/LH) contracts raise similar concerns because they <strong>in</strong>volve open<br />

ended commitments to pay for whatever quantity of labor <strong>and</strong> materials are used


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 179<br />

to accomplish the task specified <strong>in</strong> the contract. Column (4) shows that end-of-year<br />

contracts are less likely to <strong>in</strong>clude these sorts of high risk contract terms possibly<br />

because agencies are attempt<strong>in</strong>g to use up def<strong>in</strong>ed sums of excess funds <strong>and</strong> therefore<br />

limit contracts to the available amounts. The use of T&M/LH contracts <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

by 0.4 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts, which is substantial compared to a base of 5.5 percent.<br />

Because T&M/LH contracts are <strong>in</strong>frequent, column (6) shows a net decrease <strong>in</strong> the<br />

comb<strong>in</strong>ed use of risky cost-reimbursement <strong>and</strong> T&M/LH contract spend<strong>in</strong>g of about<br />

3 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts on a base of 36 percent.<br />

Overall, the analysis <strong>in</strong> this section does not offer any clear <strong>in</strong>sights <strong>in</strong>to what<br />

might be caus<strong>in</strong>g lower performance among end-of-year contracts. There is no reason<br />

to expect it to be a s<strong>in</strong>gle mechanism. All three mechanisms could be re<strong>in</strong>forc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

each other <strong>in</strong> contribut<strong>in</strong>g to the phenomenon.<br />

4.5 Do Rollover Provisions Raise Spend<strong>in</strong>g Qual-<br />

ity?<br />

The third prediction of the model is that allow<strong>in</strong>g for the rollover of unused fund<strong>in</strong>g<br />

unambiguously improves quality, both overall <strong>and</strong> at year’s end. Intuitively, organi-<br />

zations are less likely to engage <strong>in</strong> wasteful year-end spend<strong>in</strong>g when the fund<strong>in</strong>g could<br />

be used for higher value projects <strong>in</strong> the next budget period.<br />

As we noted <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>troduction, s<strong>in</strong>ce 1992 the Department of Justice (DOJ)<br />

has had special authority to roll over unused funds to pay for future I.T. needs. In<br />

this section of the paper, we exam<strong>in</strong>e whether the quality of DOJ’s end-of-year I.T.<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g is higher than that of federal agencies who lack rollover authority.<br />

4.5.1 The DOJ’s Rollover Authority<br />

The DOJ authority provides that “unobligated balances of appropriations available<br />

to the Department of Justice dur<strong>in</strong>g such fiscal year may be transferred <strong>in</strong>to the<br />

capital account of the Work<strong>in</strong>g Capital Fund to be available for the department-wide<br />

acquisition of capital equipment, development <strong>and</strong> implementation of law enforcement


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 180<br />

or litigation related automated data process<strong>in</strong>g systems, <strong>and</strong> for the improvement<br />

<strong>and</strong> implementation of the Department’s f<strong>in</strong>ancial management <strong>and</strong> payroll/personnel<br />

systems.” 22 While other agencies have ongo<strong>in</strong>g work<strong>in</strong>g capital funds, appropriated<br />

funds contributed to those funds reta<strong>in</strong> their fiscal year restrictions.<br />

Between 1992 <strong>and</strong> 2006, approximately $1.8 billion <strong>in</strong> annual appropriations were<br />

transferred to the DOJ work<strong>in</strong>g capital fund from unused appropriations balances (?).<br />

Nonetheless, Table 4.2 shows that DOJ has an end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g surge comparable<br />

to that of other agencies when all spend<strong>in</strong>g is taken <strong>in</strong>to account, with 9.4 percent of<br />

its spend<strong>in</strong>g occurr<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the last week of the year.<br />

Even with rollover authority, there rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives for agencies to use up their<br />

full allocation of fund<strong>in</strong>g. Large balances carried over from one period to another<br />

are likely to be <strong>in</strong>terpreted by OMB <strong>and</strong> Congressional appropriators as a signal that<br />

budget resources are excessive <strong>and</strong> lead to reduced budgets <strong>in</strong> subsequent periods.<br />

For example, Senator Coburn issued a report <strong>in</strong> 2008 entitled “Justice Denied: Waste<br />

<strong>and</strong> Management at the Department of Justice” <strong>in</strong> which he stated: “Every year<br />

Congress appropriates more than $20 billion for the Department of Justice to carry<br />

out its mission, <strong>and</strong> every year the Department ends the year with billions of unspent<br />

dollars. But <strong>in</strong>stead of return<strong>in</strong>g this unneeded <strong>and</strong> unspent money to the taxpayers,<br />

DOJ rolls it over year to year, essentially ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g a billion dollar bank account<br />

that it can dip <strong>in</strong>to for projects for which the money was not orig<strong>in</strong>ally <strong>in</strong>tended”<br />

(?). 23<br />

It is not just external pressure that may lead an <strong>organization</strong> to spend all of its<br />

resources even <strong>in</strong> the presence of rollover authority. Components of an agency may<br />

not be will<strong>in</strong>g to return resources to the center if they are not ensured of be<strong>in</strong>g able<br />

to spend those resources after they are rolled over. Indeed, <strong>in</strong> 2006 testimony before<br />

22 Public Law 102-104: 28 USC 527 note.<br />

23 Coburn goes on to add “. . . perhaps without the pressure to rush to spend funds before<br />

they are canceled, DOJ may, <strong>in</strong> fact, make more prudent spend<strong>in</strong>g decisions with unobligated funds.<br />

This has not been studied <strong>and</strong> warrants exam<strong>in</strong>ation for potential cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs across the federal<br />

government. As long as DOJ is bank<strong>in</strong>g billions of dollars from year to year that the Department<br />

has some discretion to spend on its priorities as they arise, however, Congress should more carefully<br />

review how much it is appropriat<strong>in</strong>g for DOJ programs. If a particular <strong>in</strong>itiative or office does not<br />

need or spend as much as Congress has appropriated, then Congress should consider appropriat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

less for that particular office <strong>and</strong> the Department overall.”


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 181<br />

Congress, Deputy Assistant Attorney General Lee Lofthus may have been suggest<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a connection between those components of DOJ that contribute expir<strong>in</strong>g funds to the<br />

work<strong>in</strong>g capital fund <strong>and</strong> those that benefit from it when he noted that the FBI was<br />

both the biggest contributor to the fund <strong>and</strong> the biggest beneficiary (?).<br />

Given that rollover funds at DOJ are used for I.T. purposes, one might expect<br />

to see little or no end-of-year spike <strong>in</strong> I.T. spend<strong>in</strong>g, because I.T. components of<br />

the agency will know that they will directly benefit from funds contributed to the<br />

work<strong>in</strong>g capital fund. This is <strong>in</strong>deed the case. In the comprehensive FPDS data,<br />

only 3.4 percent of DOJ’s I.T. spend<strong>in</strong>g occurs <strong>in</strong> the last week—the 19th lowest of<br />

the 21 major agencies. In the I.T. dashboard data, DOJ has 16 ongo<strong>in</strong>g major I.T.<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments, with planned total spend<strong>in</strong>g of just over $5.1 billion. Only 1 <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

occurred <strong>in</strong> the last week of year. The $99 million cost of this <strong>in</strong>vestment implies<br />

that 1.9 percent of DOJ spend<strong>in</strong>g occurred <strong>in</strong> the last week compared to an average<br />

of 11.0 percent across the other agencies.<br />

Although the sample size of <strong>in</strong>vestments is very small, the quality of DOJ’s year-<br />

end spend<strong>in</strong>g is high. The one last week <strong>in</strong>vestment has the highest quality score of all<br />

major I.T. <strong>in</strong>vestments at the agency. Difference-<strong>in</strong>-differences estimates presented <strong>in</strong><br />

Table 4.8, which allow us to control for <strong>in</strong>vestment characteristics, suggest that the<br />

DOJ pattern is sufficiently unusual to be statistically significant—even though it is<br />

identified off of a s<strong>in</strong>gle end-of-year observation. Specifically, difference-<strong>in</strong>-differences<br />

po<strong>in</strong>t estimates <strong>in</strong>dicate that year-end quality <strong>in</strong>creases by 2.0 to 3.5 categorical levels<br />

at DOJ relative to other agencies. The p-values on the <strong>in</strong>teraction variable are less<br />

than 0.01 <strong>in</strong> all specifications.<br />

Despite the statistical <strong>and</strong> economic significance of the estimates, we are hesitant<br />

to draw strong conclusions from the estimated effect. In addition to the small number<br />

of projects, the fact that the effect is identified off of a s<strong>in</strong>gle agency raises the potential<br />

for bias from unobserved <strong>organization</strong>al characteristics. Nevertheless, the evidence<br />

that exists appears consistent with the prediction that rollover <strong>in</strong>creases year-end<br />

quality.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 182<br />

4.6 Conclusion<br />

Our model of an <strong>organization</strong> fac<strong>in</strong>g a fixed period <strong>in</strong> which it must spend its budget<br />

resources made three predictions. We have confirmed all three of them us<strong>in</strong>g data on<br />

U.S. federal contract<strong>in</strong>g. First, there is a surge of spend<strong>in</strong>g at the end of the year.<br />

Second, end of year spend<strong>in</strong>g is of lower quality. Third, permitt<strong>in</strong>g the rollover of<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to subsequent periods leads to higher quality.<br />

Because we cannot identify the exact mechanism produc<strong>in</strong>g the decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

quality at the end of the year, it is difficult to draw firm policy conclusions from the<br />

result. If the low spend<strong>in</strong>g quality comes from agencies squ<strong>and</strong>er<strong>in</strong>g end of year<br />

resources on low priority projects, possibly compounded by <strong>in</strong>sufficient management<br />

attention dur<strong>in</strong>g the end of year spend<strong>in</strong>g rush, then allow<strong>in</strong>g for rollover of unused<br />

balances or switch<strong>in</strong>g to two-year budget<strong>in</strong>g might improve spend<strong>in</strong>g quality. But as<br />

long as future agency budgets are based <strong>in</strong> part on whether agencies exhausted their<br />

resources <strong>in</strong> the current period, there will still be an <strong>in</strong>centive for year-end spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

surges. And unless the rollover balances stay with the same part of the <strong>organization</strong><br />

that managed to save them, agency subcomponents will still have an <strong>in</strong>centive to<br />

use up their allocations. An alternative approach would be to apply greater scrut<strong>in</strong>y<br />

to end-of-the-year spend<strong>in</strong>g with the presumption that any spend<strong>in</strong>g above levels<br />

occurr<strong>in</strong>g earlier <strong>in</strong> the year was unwarranted. This latter approach could also be the<br />

proper management prescription if low quality end-of-year spend<strong>in</strong>g results from a<br />

correlation between acquisition officer skill <strong>and</strong> a tendency to procrast<strong>in</strong>ate—agencies<br />

would want to give greater attention to end of year contracts because the acquisition<br />

officials responsible for them need more oversight.<br />

In evaluat<strong>in</strong>g possible policy reforms one should not lose sight of the potential<br />

benefits of one-year budget periods. The annual appropriations cycle may provide<br />

benefits from greater Congressional control over executive branch operations. More-<br />

over, the use-it-or-lose it feature of appropriated funds may push projects out the<br />

door that would otherwise languish due to bureaucratic delays.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 183<br />

Figure 4.1: Federal Contract<strong>in</strong>g by Week, Pooled 2004 to 2009 FPDS<br />

Spend<strong>in</strong>g (billions)<br />

Number of contracts (thous<strong>and</strong>s)<br />

$250<br />

$200<br />

$150<br />

$100<br />

$50<br />

$-<br />

800<br />

600<br />

400<br />

200<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 910111213141516171819202122232425262728293031323334353637383940414243444546474849505152<br />

Week<br />

(a) Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 910111213141516171819202122232425262728293031323334353637383940414243444546474849505152<br />

Week<br />

(b) Number of Contracts<br />

Source: Federal Procurement Data System, accessed October, 2010 via<br />

www.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov.<br />

Note: Total spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> number of contracts by week of the fiscal year. Spend<strong>in</strong>g values<br />

<strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2009 dollars us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 184<br />

20 25 30 35<br />

Last quarter spend<strong>in</strong>g (percent)<br />

Non-defense<br />

2005<br />

2001<br />

2007<br />

2004<br />

Figure 4.2: Year-End Spend<strong>in</strong>g by Appropriations Date<br />

2003<br />

2006<br />

2008<br />

2002<br />

2000<br />

2000<br />

2005<br />

2008<br />

2001<br />

2006<br />

2002<br />

2004<br />

2007<br />

2003<br />

2009<br />

Defense<br />

-10 0 10 20 30<br />

Weeks late<br />

2009<br />

Non-defense slope = .193 (.094)<br />

Defense slope = .180 (.053)<br />

Pooled slope = .183 (.044)<br />

(a) Last Quarter Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

6 8 10 12 14 16<br />

Last week spend<strong>in</strong>g (percent)<br />

Non-defense slope = .112 (.146)<br />

Defense slope = .081 (.045)<br />

Pooled slope = .089 (.047)<br />

2005<br />

2007<br />

Defense<br />

2004<br />

2006<br />

2008<br />

2005<br />

10 15 20<br />

Last month spend<strong>in</strong>g (percent)<br />

2008<br />

2006<br />

2001<br />

2005<br />

Non-defense<br />

2006<br />

2003<br />

2007<br />

2004<br />

2008<br />

2002<br />

2008<br />

2000<br />

20052001<br />

2006<br />

2000<br />

2002<br />

2004<br />

2003<br />

2007<br />

2009<br />

Defense<br />

-10 0 10 20 30<br />

Weeks late<br />

2004<br />

2007<br />

2009<br />

Non-defense slope = .130 (.078)<br />

Defense slope = .089 (.030)<br />

Pooled slope = .100 (.029)<br />

(b) Last Month Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Non-defense<br />

-10 0 10 20 30<br />

Weeks late<br />

(c) Last Week Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Source: Federal Procurement Data System, accessed October, 2010 via<br />

www.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov <strong>and</strong> Library of Congress.<br />

Note: Vertical axes show the percent of annual spend<strong>in</strong>g occur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the last quarter,<br />

month, <strong>and</strong> week of the fiscal year. Horizontal axes shows the passage dates for the<br />

non-defense <strong>and</strong> defense appropriation bills, relative to the first day of the fiscal year <strong>in</strong><br />

weeks. For defense spend<strong>in</strong>g, weeks late measures the date that the defense appropriations<br />

bill was enacted. For non-defense spend<strong>in</strong>g the date is assigned from the date of the<br />

consolidated appropriations act, or, <strong>in</strong> the case of the two years <strong>in</strong> which there was not a<br />

consolidated act, a date that is the midpo<strong>in</strong>t of the <strong>in</strong>dividual non-defense appropriations<br />

acts. Plots show fitted l<strong>in</strong>es <strong>and</strong> slope coefficients from bivariate regressions on defense<br />

<strong>and</strong> non-defense spend<strong>in</strong>g. Pooled coefficients from a regression where defense <strong>and</strong><br />

non-defense spend<strong>in</strong>g have different <strong>in</strong>tercepts but are constra<strong>in</strong>ed to have the same slope.<br />

Robust st<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses.<br />

2009<br />

2009


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 185<br />

Spend<strong>in</strong>g (millions)<br />

Number of projects<br />

$16,000<br />

$12,000<br />

100<br />

$8,000<br />

$4,000<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

$0<br />

Figure 4.3: I.T. Contract<strong>in</strong>g by Week<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 910111213141516171819202122232425262728293031323334353637383940414243444546474849505152<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7<br />

8 9101112131415<br />

16 171819202122<br />

Weeks<br />

(a) Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

23 24252627282930<br />

Weeks<br />

31 323334353637<br />

(b) Number of Projects<br />

38 39404142434445<br />

46 474849505152<br />

Source: I.T. Dashboard data, accessed March, 2010 via http://it.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov.<br />

Note: Total spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> number of I.T projects by week of the fiscal year. Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

values <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2009 dollars us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 186<br />

Figure 4.4: Year-End <strong>and</strong> Rest-of-Year Overall Rat<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

40.0%<br />

30.0%<br />

20.0%<br />

10.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

45.0%<br />

30.0%<br />

15.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

25.8%<br />

8.5%<br />

Last week<br />

Rest of year<br />

3.0%<br />

22.9%<br />

5.5%<br />

11.0%<br />

32.4%<br />

15.5%<br />

36.5%<br />

24.8%<br />

1 2 3 4 5<br />

Last week<br />

Rest of year<br />

2.9%<br />

2.1%<br />

2.8%<br />

Overall Rat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

(a) Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

25.5%<br />

24.4%<br />

37.2%<br />

40.6%<br />

26.6%<br />

1 2 3 4 5<br />

Overall Rat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

(b) Number of projects<br />

Source: I.T. Dashboard data, accessed March, 2010 via http://it.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov.<br />

Note: Overall rat<strong>in</strong>g histograms for I.T. projects orig<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the last week <strong>and</strong> rest of<br />

the year. To construct this figure, rat<strong>in</strong>gs are b<strong>in</strong>ned <strong>in</strong>to 5 categories with the lowest<br />

category represent<strong>in</strong>g overall rat<strong>in</strong>gs less than 2, the second lowest represent<strong>in</strong>g overall<br />

rat<strong>in</strong>gs between 2 <strong>and</strong> 4, <strong>and</strong> so on. See text for details on the overall rat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex. Panel<br />

A weights projects by <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted spend<strong>in</strong>g. Panel B shows unweighted values.<br />

22.6%<br />

29.3%


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 187<br />

Table 4.1: Summary Statistics: Federal Contract<strong>in</strong>g, Pooled 2004 to 2009 FPDS<br />

Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Contracts<br />

Billions Percent Count Percent<br />

Totals $2,597 100.0% 14,600,000 100.0%<br />

Year<br />

2004 $304 11.7% 1,413,316 9.7%<br />

2005 $355 13.7% 1,857,960 12.7%<br />

2006 $405 15.6% 2,719,479 18.6%<br />

2007 $452 17.4% 2,977,426 20.4%<br />

2008 $542 20.9% 3,292,063 22.5%<br />

2009 $538 20.7% 2,307,904 15.8%<br />

Contract size<br />

Less than $100K $166 6.4% 13,800,000 94.5%<br />

$100K to $1M $398 15.3% 626,134 4.3%<br />

At least $1M $2,033 78.3% 98,001 0.7%<br />

Agency<br />

Agriculture $25 1.0% 241,626 1.7%<br />

Commerce $13 0.5% 112,756 0.8%<br />

Defense $1,824 70.2% 3,536,530 24.2%<br />

Education $8 0.3% 12,806 0.1%<br />

Energy $142 5.5% 37,756 0.3%<br />

Environmental Protection Agency $8 0.3% 62,713 0.4%<br />

General Services Adm<strong>in</strong>istration $82 3.2% 4,830,748 33.1%<br />

Health <strong>and</strong> Human Services $76 2.9% 249,907 1.7%<br />

Homel<strong>and</strong> Security $74 2.8% 255,461 1.7%<br />

Hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Urban Development $6 0.2% 15,666 0.1%<br />

Interior $25 1.0% 377,743 2.6%<br />

Justice $33 1.3% 420,379 2.9%<br />

Labor $13 0.5% 41,229 0.3%<br />

National Aeronautics <strong>and</strong> Space Adm<strong>in</strong>istration $83 3.2% 81,211 0.6%<br />

National Science Foundation $2 0.1% 4,201 0.0%<br />

Other $37 1.4% 179,283 1.2%<br />

Small Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Adm<strong>in</strong>istration $0 0.0% 3,361 0.0%<br />

State $34 1.3% 239,019 1.6%<br />

Transportation $21 0.8% 57,235 0.4%<br />

Treasury $25 1.0% 177,662 1.2%<br />

Veterans Affairs $67 2.6% 3,630,856 24.9%<br />

Competition type<br />

Non-competitive $745 28.7% 3,553,453 24.3%<br />

Competitive with one bid $521 20.0% 3,883,273 26.6%<br />

Competitive with more than one bid $1,332 51.3% 7,131,422 48.8%<br />

Contract type<br />

Fixed price $1,675 64.5% 14,200,000 97.3%<br />

Cost-reimbursement $780 30.0% 151,362 1.0%<br />

Time <strong>and</strong> materials/labor hours $142 5.5% 249,705 1.7%<br />

Source: Federal Procurement Data System, accessed October, 2010 via www.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov<br />

Note: Contract spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>flation adjusted to 2009 dollars us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 188<br />

Table 4.2: Year-End Contract Spend<strong>in</strong>g by Agency, Pooled 2004 to 2009 FPDS<br />

Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Percent of spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

(billions) Last month Last week<br />

Agriculture $24.8 17.0% 6.2%<br />

Commerce $13.4 21.4% 5.6%<br />

Defense $1,820.0 16.0% 8.6%<br />

Education $8.2 18.6% 11.2%<br />

Energy $142.0 6.6% 4.0%<br />

Environmental Protection Agency $8.1 22.3% 10.4%<br />

General Services Adm<strong>in</strong>istration $82.0 12.9% 7.0%<br />

Health <strong>and</strong> Human Services $76.4 25.5% 12.2%<br />

Homel<strong>and</strong> Security $73.6 22.7% 9.4%<br />

Hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Urban Development $5.7 18.5% 11.7%<br />

Interior $25.3 23.2% 7.6%<br />

Justice $32.6 17.9% 9.4%<br />

Labor $12.7 12.9% 5.9%<br />

National Aeronautics <strong>and</strong> Space Adm<strong>in</strong>istration $82.7 16.9% 11.0%<br />

National Science Foundation $2.0 27.7% 11.5%<br />

Small Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Adm<strong>in</strong>istration $0.4 31.9% 16.3%<br />

State $33.5 34.9% 20.4%<br />

Transportation $20.5 17.6% 3.6%<br />

Treasury $24.9 15.3% 9.6%<br />

Veterans Affairs $66.9 18.2% 9.5%<br />

Other $37.4 28.6% 18.9%<br />

Total $2,600.0 16.5% 8.7%<br />

Source: Federal Procurement Data System, accessed October, 2010 via www.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov.<br />

Note: Contract spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>flation adjusted to 2009 dollars us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 189<br />

Table 4.3: Year-End Contract Spend<strong>in</strong>g By Selected Product or Service Code, Pooled<br />

2004 to 2009 FPDS<br />

Spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Percent of spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

(billions) Last month Last week<br />

Construction-related<br />

Construction of structures <strong>and</strong> facilities $136.0 40.9% 28.6%<br />

Ma<strong>in</strong>tenance, repair, or alteration of real property $72.5 34.8% 20.1%<br />

Architect <strong>and</strong> eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g services $32.8 26.1% 13.8%<br />

Installation of equipment $4.0 33.9% 20.4%<br />

Prefabricated structures <strong>and</strong> scaffold<strong>in</strong>g $3.7 34.9% 18.4%<br />

Furnish<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> office equipment<br />

Furniture $8.0 37.3% 18.4%<br />

Office supplies <strong>and</strong> devices $4.0 24.9% 16.6%<br />

Household <strong>and</strong> commercial furnish<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> appliances $1.2 37.8% 20.7%<br />

Office mach<strong>in</strong>es, text process<strong>in</strong>g systems <strong>and</strong> equipment $1.1 33.5% 17.0%<br />

I.T. services <strong>and</strong> equipment<br />

Automatic data process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> telecom. services $145.0 21.0% 12.3%<br />

Automatic data process<strong>in</strong>g equipment $53.7 29.2% 14.9%<br />

Services<br />

Professional, adm<strong>in</strong>, <strong>and</strong> management support services $336.0 19.1% 9.9%<br />

Research <strong>and</strong> development $309.0 11.3% 5.3%<br />

Utilities <strong>and</strong> housekeep<strong>in</strong>g services $73.7 15.6% 9.1%<br />

Ongo<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Fuels, lubricants, oils <strong>and</strong> waxes $72.7 13.2% 0.7%<br />

Medical services $68.8 4.9% 1.7%<br />

Chemicals <strong>and</strong> chemical products $6.2 3.3% 1.3%<br />

Tires <strong>and</strong> tubes $1.0 8.7% 2.7%<br />

Toiletries $0.3 12.2% 3.0%<br />

Military weapons systems<br />

Aircraft <strong>and</strong> airframe structural components $141.0 5.7% 2.9%<br />

Ships, small craft, pontoons, <strong>and</strong> float<strong>in</strong>g docks $48.5 7.5% 2.1%<br />

Guided missiles $38.0 8.1% 3.5%<br />

Other $1,111.6 13.6% 6.8%<br />

Total $2,600.0 16.5% 8.7%<br />

Source: Federal Procurement Data System, accessed October, 2010 via www.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov.<br />

Note: Contract spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the last month <strong>and</strong> week of the fiscal year by selected 2-digit product or service code, <strong>in</strong>flation<br />

adjusted to 2009 dollars us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U. Categories jo<strong>in</strong>tly account for 57.2 percent of total spend<strong>in</strong>g.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 190<br />

Table 4.4: Summary Statistics: Major I.T. Projects as of March, 2010<br />

IT spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

IT projects<br />

Millions Percent Count Percent<br />

Total $129,729 100.0% 686 100.0%<br />

Agency<br />

Agency for International Development $265 0.2% 3 0.4%<br />

Agriculture $1,864 1.4% 33 4.8%<br />

Commerce $11,042 8.5% 46 6.7%<br />

Corps of Eng<strong>in</strong>eers $4,012 3.1% 11 1.6%<br />

Defense $14,889 11.5% 46 6.7%<br />

Education $1,407 1.1% 25 3.6%<br />

Energy $4,914 3.8% 26 3.8%<br />

Environmental Protection Agency $3,166 2.4% 20 2.9%<br />

General Services Adm<strong>in</strong>istration $2,162 1.7% 25 3.6%<br />

Health <strong>and</strong> Human Services $8,990 6.9% 64 9.3%<br />

Homel<strong>and</strong> Security $13,068 10.1% 70 10.2%<br />

Hous<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Urban Development $1,605 1.2% 10 1.5%<br />

Interior $4,557 3.5% 39 5.7%<br />

Justice $4,376 3.4% 15 2.2%<br />

Labor $2,434 1.9% 34 5.0%<br />

National Aeronautics <strong>and</strong> Space Adm<strong>in</strong>istration $9,722 7.5% 22 3.2%<br />

National Archives <strong>and</strong> Records Adm<strong>in</strong>istration $649 0.5% 8 1.2%<br />

National Science Foundation $374 0.3% 6 0.9%<br />

Nuclear Regulatory Commission $515 0.4% 16 2.3%<br />

Office of Personnel Management $497 0.4% 7 1.0%<br />

Small Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Adm<strong>in</strong>istration $269 0.2% 9 1.3%<br />

Smithsonian Institution $58 0.0% 9 1.3%<br />

Social Security Adm<strong>in</strong>istration $1,236 1.0% 13 1.9%<br />

State $3,705 2.9% 13 1.9%<br />

Transportation $12,514 9.6% 42 6.1%<br />

Treasury $4,921 3.8% 41 6.0%<br />

Veterans Affairs $16,521 12.7% 33 4.8%<br />

Year of orig<strong>in</strong>ation<br />

1981 $2,706 2.1% 1 0.1%<br />

1991 $61 0.0% 1 0.1%<br />

1992 $322 0.2% 1 0.1%<br />

1993 $409 0.3% 2 0.3%<br />

1994 $155 0.1% 2 0.3%<br />

1996 $3,050 2.4% 7 1.0%<br />

1997 $1,430 1.1% 3 0.4%<br />

1998 $2,891 2.2% 5 0.7%<br />

1999 $2,814 2.2% 10 1.5%<br />

2000 $2,855 2.2% 15 2.2%<br />

2001 $8,463 6.5% 17 2.5%<br />

2002 $12,577 9.7% 32 4.7%<br />

2003 $13,860 10.7% 60 8.7%<br />

2004 $12,818 9.9% 87 12.7%<br />

2005 $13,529 10.4% 95 13.8%<br />

2006 $16,169 12.5% 126 18.4%<br />

2007 $17,935 13.8% 121 17.6%<br />

2008 $14,176 10.9% 75 10.9%<br />

2009 $3,508 2.7% 26 3.8%<br />

Source: I.T. Dashboard data, accessed March, 2010 via http://it.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov<br />

Notes: Major I.T. <strong>in</strong>vestments by federal agency <strong>and</strong> year of orig<strong>in</strong>ation, <strong>in</strong>flation adjusted to 2009 dollars us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 191<br />

Table 4.5: Summary Statistics: Quality Indexes <strong>and</strong> Project Characteristics for Major<br />

I.T. Projects<br />

Mean Std. Dev. M<strong>in</strong> Max<br />

Planned cost (millions) 189.11 447.06 0.10 4770.89<br />

Overall rat<strong>in</strong>g 7.07 2.30 0.00 10.00<br />

Rat<strong>in</strong>g sub<strong>in</strong>dexes<br />

CIO evaluation 3.95 0.94 1.00 5.00<br />

Cost rat<strong>in</strong>g 8.72 2.52 0.00 10.00<br />

Cost overrun 5.25 1.49 0.00 10.00<br />

Schedule rat<strong>in</strong>g 8.43 3.09 0.00 10.00<br />

Count Percent<br />

Investment phase<br />

Full-Acquisition 59 8.6%<br />

Mixed Life Cycle 304 44.3%<br />

Multi-Agency Collaboration 29 4.2%<br />

Operations <strong>and</strong> Ma<strong>in</strong>tenance 278 40.5%<br />

Plann<strong>in</strong>g 16 2.3%<br />

Service group<br />

Management of Government Resources 124 18.1%<br />

Miss<strong>in</strong>g 2 0.3%<br />

Service Types <strong>and</strong> Components 125 18.2%<br />

Services for Citizens 344 50.2%<br />

Support Delivery of Services to Citizen 91 13.3%<br />

L<strong>in</strong>e of bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

Adm<strong>in</strong>istrative Management 15 2.2%<br />

Controls <strong>and</strong> Oversight 12 1.8%<br />

Defense <strong>and</strong> National Security 30 4.4%<br />

Disaster Management 20 2.9%<br />

Economic Development 9 1.3%<br />

Education 16 2.3%<br />

Energy 5 0.7%<br />

Environmental Management 32 4.7%<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ancial Management 81 11.8%<br />

General Government [CA] 45 6.6%<br />

General Science <strong>and</strong> Innovation 22 3.2%<br />

Health 55 8.0%<br />

Homel<strong>and</strong> Security 40 5.8%<br />

Human Resource Management 24 3.5%<br />

Income Security 17 2.5%<br />

Information <strong>and</strong> Technology Management 85 12.4%<br />

International Affairs <strong>and</strong> Commerce 7 1.0%<br />

Law Enforcement 12 1.8%<br />

Natural Resources 16 2.3%<br />

Plann<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Budget<strong>in</strong>g 8 1.2%<br />

Public Affairs 13 1.9%<br />

Revenue Collection 8 1.2%<br />

Supply Cha<strong>in</strong> Management 25 3.6%<br />

Transportation 45 6.6%<br />

Workforce Management 5 0.7%<br />

Other 39 5.7%<br />

Total 686 100.0%<br />

Source: I.T. Dashboard data, accessed March, 2010 via http://it.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov<br />

Notes: Planned total cost is <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted to 2009 dollars us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U. Overall rat<strong>in</strong>g is a quality <strong>in</strong>dex that comb<strong>in</strong>es that<br />

CIO evaluation, cost rat<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong> schedul<strong>in</strong>g rat<strong>in</strong>g sub<strong>in</strong>dexes (see text for details). It takes values from 0 to 10, with 10 be<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

best score. The CIO evaluation is the agency CIO's assessment of project quality. It takes values from 1 to 5, with 5 be<strong>in</strong>g the best.<br />

The cost rat<strong>in</strong>g is based on the absolute percent deviation between the planned <strong>and</strong> actual cost of the project. The cost overrun is a<br />

non-absolute measure that assigns over-cost projects the lowest scores. The schedule rat<strong>in</strong>g is based on the average tard<strong>in</strong>ess of<br />

the project. The cost <strong>and</strong> schedule <strong>in</strong>dexes takes values from 0 to 10, with 10 be<strong>in</strong>g the best. The l<strong>in</strong>e of bus<strong>in</strong>ess other category<br />

comb<strong>in</strong>es all categories with 4 or fewer projects.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 192<br />

Table 4.6: Ordered Logit Regressions of Overall Rat<strong>in</strong>g on Last Week <strong>and</strong> Controls<br />

Odds ratio of higher overall rat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

Last week 0.26 0.46 0.30 0.18<br />

(0.07) (0.14) (0.10) (0.07)<br />

Year FE X X X<br />

Agency FE X X<br />

Project characteristics FE X<br />

N 671 671 671 671<br />

Source: I.T. Dashboard data, accessed March, 2010 via http://it.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov<br />

Notes: Odds ratios from ordered logit regressions. Overall rat<strong>in</strong>g is a quality <strong>in</strong>dex that<br />

comb<strong>in</strong>es that CIO evaluation, cost rat<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong> schedul<strong>in</strong>g rat<strong>in</strong>g sub<strong>in</strong>dexes (see text for<br />

details). It takes values from 0 to 10, with 10 be<strong>in</strong>g the best score. Project characteristics are<br />

fixed effects for <strong>in</strong>vestment phase, service group, <strong>and</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e of bus<strong>in</strong>ess (see Table 5).<br />

Observations weighted by <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted spend<strong>in</strong>g. St<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 193<br />

Table 4.7: Alternative Overall Rat<strong>in</strong>gs Specifications<br />

Odds ratio of higher overall rat<strong>in</strong>g from ordered logit Coefficients from l<strong>in</strong>ear model<br />

W<strong>in</strong>sorized<br />

Heckman<br />

Contracts < $62M Contracts ≥ $62M Unweighted weights OLS selection model<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

Last week 0.60 0.18 0.56 0.37 -1.00 -1.57<br />

(0.23) (0.11) (0.14) (0.12) (0.39) (0.64)<br />

Year FE X X X X X<br />

Agency FE X X X X X X<br />

Project characteristics X X X X X X<br />

Weighted by spend<strong>in</strong>g X X X X X<br />

! -0.87<br />

(0.85)<br />

R-squared 0.69<br />

N 335 336 671 671 671 3,803<br />

Source: I.T. Dashboard data, accessed March, 2010 via http://it.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov <strong>and</strong> 2003 to 2010 Exhibit 53 reports, available<br />

at http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/e-gov/docs/.<br />

Notes: Columns (1) to (4) show odds ratios from ordered logit regressions. Columns (1) <strong>and</strong> (2) split the sample at the median<br />

value. Column (3) shows odds ratios from an unweighted regression. Column (4) W<strong>in</strong>sorizes the spend<strong>in</strong>g weight at $1 billion<br />

(96th percentile).Columns (5) <strong>and</strong> (6) show regression coefficients from l<strong>in</strong>ear regressions. Column (5) reports coefficients from<br />

a simple OLS regression. Column (6) reports coefficient from a Heckman selection model with a l<strong>in</strong>ear second stage. In this<br />

regression the sample is all major I.T. projects recorded <strong>in</strong> the Exhibit 53 reports. The excluded variable <strong>in</strong> this selection model<br />

is the year of project orig<strong>in</strong>ation. The coefficient ! is the implied coefficient on the <strong>in</strong>verse Mill's ratio selection term. Overall<br />

rat<strong>in</strong>g is a quality <strong>in</strong>dex that comb<strong>in</strong>es that CIO evaluation, cost rat<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong> schedul<strong>in</strong>g rat<strong>in</strong>g sub<strong>in</strong>dexes (see text for details).<br />

It takes values from 0 to 10, with 10 be<strong>in</strong>g the best score. Project characteristics are fixed effects for <strong>in</strong>vestment phase, service<br />

group, <strong>and</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e of bus<strong>in</strong>ess (see Table 5). Observations weighted by <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted spend<strong>in</strong>g unless otherwise mentioned.<br />

Robust st<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 194<br />

Table 4.8: Difference-<strong>in</strong>-Differences Estimates of Overall Rat<strong>in</strong>g on Justice <strong>and</strong> Last<br />

Week<br />

OLS Estimates<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

Justice X last week 3.54 2.29 2.85 2.36 2.251 2.49<br />

(1.19) (1.16) (0.75) (0.65) 0.593 0.898<br />

Last week -1.91 -1.06 -0.93 -0.99 -0.814 -0.468<br />

(1.10) (0.82) (0.48) (0.39) 0.391 0.238<br />

Justice 0.06 -0.59 -3.33 -3.88 -4.022 -2.028<br />

(0.51) (0.49) (0.47) (0.59) 0.578 1.01<br />

Year FE X X X X X<br />

Agency FE X X X X<br />

Project characteristics X X X<br />

Weighted by spend<strong>in</strong>g X X X X W<strong>in</strong>sorized*<br />

R-squared 0.06 0.22 0.58 0.68 0.60 0.48<br />

N 686 686 686 686 686 686<br />

Source: I.T. Dashboard data, accessed March, 2010 via http://it.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov<br />

Notes: Coefficients from OLS regressions of overall rat<strong>in</strong>g on fully <strong>in</strong>teracted Justice <strong>and</strong> last week<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicators <strong>and</strong> controls. Overall rat<strong>in</strong>g is a quality <strong>in</strong>dex that comb<strong>in</strong>es that CIO evaluation, cost rat<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

<strong>and</strong> schedul<strong>in</strong>g rat<strong>in</strong>g sub<strong>in</strong>dexes (see text for details). It takes values from 0 to 10, with 10 be<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

best score. Project characteristics are fixed effects for <strong>in</strong>vestment phase, service group, <strong>and</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e of<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess (see Table 5). Robust st<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses.<br />

*Spend<strong>in</strong>g weight W<strong>in</strong>sorized at $1 billion (96th percentile).


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 195<br />

Table 4.9: First Week Contract Spend<strong>in</strong>g for Selected Product or Service Codes,<br />

Pooled 2004 to 2009 FPDS<br />

Spend<strong>in</strong>g First week<br />

(billions) (percent)<br />

Leases<br />

Lease or rental of facilities $29.2 26.2%<br />

Lease or rental of equipment $5.4 13.1%<br />

Service contracts<br />

Utilities <strong>and</strong> housekeep<strong>in</strong>g services $73.7 11.1%<br />

Medical services $68.8 11.3%<br />

Transportation, travel <strong>and</strong> relocation services $39.3 15.5%<br />

Social services $5.5 9.3%<br />

Other $2,378.1 3.1%<br />

Total $2,600.0 4.0%<br />

Source: Federal Procurement Data System, accessed October, 2010 via www.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov<br />

Note: Percent of contract spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the last month <strong>and</strong> week of the fiscal year by selected 2digit<br />

product or service code, <strong>in</strong>flation adjusted to 2009 dollars us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U. Categories<br />

account for about 8.5% of spend<strong>in</strong>g but 29.7% of first week spend<strong>in</strong>g.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 196<br />

Table 4.10: Ordered Logit Regressions of Sub<strong>in</strong>dexes on Last Week <strong>and</strong> Controls<br />

Odds ratio from ordered logit<br />

Evalutation by Agency Cost Cost Schedule<br />

CIO<br />

rat<strong>in</strong>g overrun rat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)<br />

Last week of September 0.14 0.16 0.80 0.74 1.15<br />

(0.06) (0.07) (0.36) (0.30) (0.66)<br />

Cost <strong>and</strong> schedule rat<strong>in</strong>g X<br />

Agency FE X X X X X<br />

Year FE X X X X X<br />

Project characteristics X X X X X<br />

Weighted by spend<strong>in</strong>g X X X X X<br />

N 671 671 671 671 671<br />

Source: I.T. Dashboard data, accessed March, 2010 via http://it.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov<br />

Notes: Odds ratios from ordered logit regressions. The CIO evaluation is the agency CIO's<br />

assessment of project quality. It takes values from 1 to 5, with 5 be<strong>in</strong>g the best. The cost<br />

rat<strong>in</strong>g is based on the absolute percent deviation between the planned <strong>and</strong> actual cost of<br />

the project. The cost overrun is a non-absolute measure that assigns over-cost projects the<br />

lowest scores. The schedule rat<strong>in</strong>g is based on the average tard<strong>in</strong>ess of the project. The<br />

cost <strong>and</strong> schedule <strong>in</strong>dexes takes values from 0 to 10, with 10 be<strong>in</strong>g the best. Project<br />

characteristics are fixed effects for <strong>in</strong>vestment phase, service group, <strong>and</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e of bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

(see Table 5). St<strong>and</strong>ard errors <strong>in</strong> parentheses.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 197<br />

Table 4.11: Year-End Contract Characteristics Regressions<br />

Dependent Variable:<br />

Cost-<br />

Non-competitive Costreimbursement<br />

or<br />

Non-competitive One bid<br />

or one bid reimbursement T&M/LH<br />

T&M/LH<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

Last week -0.002 0.017 0.010 -0.032 0.004 -0.028<br />

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002)<br />

Year FE X X X X X X<br />

Agency FE X X X X X X<br />

Product or service code FE X X X X X X<br />

R-squared 0.41 0.31 0.30 0.52 0.21 0.51<br />

N 402,400 402,400 402,400 402,400 402,400 402,400<br />

Mean of dependent variable 28.7% 20.0% 48.7% 30.0% 5.5% 35.5%<br />

Source: Federal Procurement Data System, accessed October, 2010 via www.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov<br />

Note: Table shows coefficients from l<strong>in</strong>ear probability model regressions of contract type <strong>and</strong> competition type <strong>in</strong>dicators on last week<br />

<strong>and</strong> controls. To facility the analysis, the data is aggregated to the level of the covariates <strong>and</strong> the regressions are weighted by<br />

<strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> each cell.


CHAPTER 4. YEAR-END SPENDING 198<br />

Table 4.12: Percent of Projects <strong>in</strong> I.T. Dashboard Data<br />

Spend<strong>in</strong>g Projects<br />

All I.T Dashboard<br />

% <strong>in</strong> I.T.<br />

Dashboard All I.T Dashboard<br />

% <strong>in</strong> I.T.<br />

Dashboard<br />

Year of orig<strong>in</strong><br />

≤ 2001 $68,460 $14,538 21.2% 813 48 5.9%<br />

2002 $114,668 $12,848 11.2% 1,018 61 6.0%<br />

2003 $115,286 $51,004 44.2% 653 113 17.3%<br />

2004 $53,151 $10,309 19.4% 467 71 15.2%<br />

2005 $35,027 $16,456 47.0% 250 56 22.4%<br />

2006 $13,023 $5,172 39.7% 191 77 40.3%<br />

2007 $61,953 $55,665 89.8% 248 183 73.8%<br />

2008 $19,864 $19,752 99.4% 135 127 94.1%<br />

2009 $498 $491 98.7% 16 13 81.3%<br />

2010 $285 $273 95.5% 13 10 76.9%<br />

Total $482,215 $186,509 38.7% 3,803 759 20.0%<br />

Source: I.T. Dashboard data, accessed March, 2010 via http://it.usaspend<strong>in</strong>g.gov <strong>and</strong> 2003 to 2010<br />

Exhibit 53 reports, available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/e-gov/docs/.<br />

Notes: All spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> projects are totals from agency Exhibit 53 reports. I.T. Dashboard spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong><br />

projects are totals <strong>in</strong> the I.T. Dashboard dataset (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g projects dropped from the basel<strong>in</strong>e sample due<br />

to miss<strong>in</strong>g values). Spend<strong>in</strong>g values <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted us<strong>in</strong>g the CPI-U.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!