20.01.2013 Views

Taskforce on Industry Self-Regulation Draft Report - Australian ...

Taskforce on Industry Self-Regulation Draft Report - Australian ...

Taskforce on Industry Self-Regulation Draft Report - Australian ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>Industry</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-Regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>Draft</strong> <strong>Report</strong><br />

June 2000


ISBN 0 642 74031 3<br />

This publicati<strong>on</strong> may be freely reproduced provided suitable acknowledgement is<br />

made. Copies of this publicati<strong>on</strong> may be obtained from the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs<br />

Divisi<strong>on</strong>, Department of the Treasury at the following address.<br />

Treasury Building<br />

Parkes Place<br />

PARKES ACT 2600<br />

Ph: (02) 6263 2936<br />

Fax: (02) 6263 2830<br />

Email: selfregtaskforce@treasury.gov.au<br />

Internet: http://www.treasury.gov.au/self-regtaskforce<br />

Printed by


Background<br />

Terms of Reference<br />

I. As part of the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth’s electi<strong>on</strong> policy commitment to encourage<br />

industry to develop effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> approaches, the Minister for<br />

Financial Services & Regulati<strong>on</strong> has set up a <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-Regulati<strong>on</strong> to<br />

inquire into and report <strong>on</strong> aspects of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets. The<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> is also to have regard to the recommendati<strong>on</strong>s of the<br />

Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Interdepartmental Committee <strong>on</strong> Quasi-regulati<strong>on</strong> released<br />

in December 1997 (the Grey Letter Law report) and the Codes of C<strong>on</strong>duct Policy<br />

Framework released by the then Minister with resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

affairs in March 1998.<br />

II. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sists of representatives from a range of industry and<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups.<br />

III. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> includes those regulatory regimes which have been generally<br />

developed by industry (sometimes in cooperati<strong>on</strong> with government but<br />

enforced exclusively by industry). <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> excludes explicit<br />

government legislati<strong>on</strong> and regulati<strong>on</strong> as well as regulati<strong>on</strong> developed by<br />

government and handed over to industry for implementati<strong>on</strong>, although for<br />

the purposes of this <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> it could include co-regulati<strong>on</strong>, where a scheme<br />

is developed by industry with some government involvement but industry is<br />

fully resp<strong>on</strong>sible for its implementati<strong>on</strong>. Examples of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> include:<br />

¾ Individual businesses choosing to adopt a standard;<br />

¾ Private instituti<strong>on</strong>s regulating themselves by a set of rules; and the<br />

¾ Introducti<strong>on</strong> by industry participants of an industry-wide regulatory code.<br />

IV. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> could also include professi<strong>on</strong>al bodies’ codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct,<br />

industry service charters, guidelines and standards, as well as industry based<br />

accreditati<strong>on</strong> and complaint handling schemes.<br />

V. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is increasingly being used as an alternative to quasi-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

and government legislati<strong>on</strong> and there is some overlap between them.<br />

Identifying best practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, and identifying the limits of<br />

self-regulatory schemes, has important implicati<strong>on</strong>s for the Government’s<br />

approach toward a more efficient regulatory framework for both businesses<br />

and c<strong>on</strong>sumers. The role of government in encouraging self-regulati<strong>on</strong> also<br />

has an impact <strong>on</strong> compliance costs, flexibility and the coverage of<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

i


VI. The Government is committed to providing a competitive market<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment while attempting to reduce the regulatory burden <strong>on</strong> <strong>Australian</strong><br />

business. <strong>Industry</strong> self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is often a more flexible alternative to direct<br />

government regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

VII. However, it is necessary to ensure that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> does not itself become a<br />

burden to industry with <strong>on</strong>erous compliance costs, particularly for small<br />

businesses. It is also necessary to minimise the anti-competitive potential of<br />

industry self-regulatory schemes by ensuring that such schemes do not set up<br />

barriers to entry to the industry, nor stifle innovati<strong>on</strong> or competiti<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>gst<br />

industry participants. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is not appropriate in circumstances<br />

where other forms of regulati<strong>on</strong> are able to provide better outcomes at a<br />

lower cost.<br />

ii


Terms of Reference<br />

1. The Government has an objective of lowering regulatory costs <strong>on</strong> business,<br />

improving market outcomes for c<strong>on</strong>sumers and encouraging self-regulati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

including promoting quality codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct in c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets. The<br />

Government also has the objective that industry should take increased<br />

ownership and resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for developing efficient and effective<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> where it is the most appropriate regulatory resp<strong>on</strong>se.<br />

2. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is to inquire into and report <strong>on</strong> aspects of<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> pertinent to those objectives, including:<br />

(a) the types of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in use in c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets in Australia;<br />

(b) gaps and overlaps in the coverage of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>;<br />

(c) those industry envir<strong>on</strong>ments and market circumstances where different<br />

types of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> are likely to be most effective;<br />

(d) best practice and cost-effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> methods and approaches;<br />

(e) approaches to promoting and coordinating industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

including the appropriate role of government and the development of<br />

industry codes as well as other approaches to self-regulati<strong>on</strong>; and<br />

(f) opti<strong>on</strong>s that facilitate the improvement and harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of dispute<br />

resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes while reducing costs to industry and improving<br />

outcomes for c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

3. The report is to address the effectiveness of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> including the<br />

identificati<strong>on</strong> of where different forms of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> have worked well<br />

and why and aspects of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> requiring more attenti<strong>on</strong>. This will<br />

include identifying cost-effective best practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

4. In undertaking its inquiry, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> will:<br />

(a) focus <strong>on</strong> self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets where the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth<br />

Government has c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al resp<strong>on</strong>sibility or where there is a<br />

nati<strong>on</strong>al scheme in place;<br />

(b) n<strong>on</strong>etheless, have regard to the changing regulatory envir<strong>on</strong>ment and,<br />

in particular, developments in industry self-regulatory practice in other<br />

jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s within Australia and overseas;<br />

iii


(c) recognise the dynamics of <strong>Australian</strong> markets, particularly the impact of<br />

globalisati<strong>on</strong>, increasing vertical integrati<strong>on</strong>, and the growth of ‘hybrid’<br />

products that span traditi<strong>on</strong>al markets or industries, noting the implied<br />

challenges for industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>;<br />

(d) undertake appropriate c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s, including with peak business<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>s, small business groups, c<strong>on</strong>sumer representatives and<br />

government bodies;<br />

(e) publish a draft report with recommendati<strong>on</strong>s for comment and criticism<br />

by interested parties; and<br />

(f) present a final report with recommendati<strong>on</strong>s to the Minister for<br />

Financial Services & Regulati<strong>on</strong> no later than 31 May 2000 (extended to<br />

31 August 2000).<br />

5. The Minister will seek to use the findings of the inquiry to promote efficient<br />

and competitive markets. However, any outcomes from the inquiry would<br />

themselves be subject to c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> and regulatory impact analysis.<br />

iv


Members of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Industry</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-Regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

Berna Collier (chair)<br />

Professor of Commercial Law<br />

Centre for Commercial and Property Law<br />

Queensland University of Technology<br />

Peter Daly<br />

Chair<br />

Insurance Enquiries and Complaints Ltd Board<br />

Marina Darling<br />

Managing Director<br />

Cap<strong>on</strong>ero Group<br />

Rob Edwards<br />

Chief Executive Officer<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

Ella Keenan<br />

Nati<strong>on</strong>al President<br />

Business and Professi<strong>on</strong>al Women of Australia<br />

Mark Paters<strong>on</strong><br />

Chief Executive<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> Chamber of Commerce and <strong>Industry</strong><br />

Johanna Plante<br />

Chief Executive Officer<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Forum<br />

Gary Potts<br />

Executive Director<br />

The Treasury<br />

Louise Sylvan<br />

Chief Executive<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

v


C<strong>on</strong>tents<br />

Executive summary 1<br />

Chapter 1: Introducti<strong>on</strong> 9<br />

Inquiry process 9<br />

Structure of report 11<br />

Chapter 2: Framework for the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> Inquiry 13<br />

Analytical tools for identifying lowest cost-effective opti<strong>on</strong>s 14<br />

Catalysts for industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> 15<br />

Choosing the appropriate soluti<strong>on</strong> from the spectrum<br />

of self-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>s 17<br />

The advantages of industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to address market failure 18<br />

Chapter 3: Types of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets in Australia 20<br />

Reas<strong>on</strong>s for self-regulati<strong>on</strong> 21<br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>s available to industry 24<br />

Chapter 4: Gaps and overlaps in the coverage of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> 29<br />

C<strong>on</strong>verging sectors and product lines 30<br />

Globalisati<strong>on</strong> 30<br />

Gaps in the market 31<br />

Overlap in the market 36<br />

Chapter 5: <strong>Industry</strong> envir<strong>on</strong>ment and market circumstances where<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be most effective 39<br />

Office of Regulati<strong>on</strong> Review checklist 41<br />

Nature and extent of market failure 42<br />

Market Structure 43<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>sumer interests 47<br />

Chapter 6: Good practice and cost-effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> methods 55<br />

Good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> 58<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> 58<br />

Coverage and publicity 61<br />

Administrati<strong>on</strong> 64<br />

Dispute procedures and sancti<strong>on</strong>s 67<br />

M<strong>on</strong>itoring and reviewing 73<br />

Cost-effective practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> 75<br />

vii


Chapter 7: Approaches to promoting and coordinating<br />

industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> 83<br />

Role of industry 85<br />

Role of Government 86<br />

Role of c<strong>on</strong>sumers 98<br />

Oversight committee 101<br />

Developing a model code of practice 103<br />

Chapter 8: Opti<strong>on</strong>s that facilitate the improvement and<br />

harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes 105<br />

Range of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes 106<br />

Potential for dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes to operate across<br />

different sectors with similar products/services 107<br />

Shared case management/dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms 109<br />

Promoting dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes 109<br />

Appendix A: List of submissi<strong>on</strong>s 113<br />

Appendix B: List of parties c<strong>on</strong>sulted 115<br />

Appendix C: Regulatory framework for industry codes in Australia 119<br />

Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth framework for codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct 120<br />

State and Territory framework for codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct 123<br />

Examples of industry codes supported by legislati<strong>on</strong> 124<br />

Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s sector 125<br />

Health sector 127<br />

Other review mechanisms 128<br />

Nati<strong>on</strong>al privacy principles 129<br />

Summary and overview 132<br />

Appendix D: Internati<strong>on</strong>al Policy <strong>on</strong> <strong>Industry</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> 133<br />

Introducti<strong>on</strong> 133<br />

OECD research 134<br />

The United States of America (US) 135<br />

Canada 137<br />

United Kingdom 139<br />

New Zealand 141<br />

European Uni<strong>on</strong> 141<br />

Electr<strong>on</strong>ic commerce (e-commerce) case study 142<br />

Future trends in internati<strong>on</strong>al self-regulatory policy 145<br />

viii


Executive summary<br />

The Government has an objective of lowering regulatory costs <strong>on</strong> business and<br />

improving market outcomes for c<strong>on</strong>sumers, by encouraging self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, where<br />

this is the most effective opti<strong>on</strong> for addressing an identified problem. The<br />

Government also has the objective that industry should take increased ownership<br />

and resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for developing efficient and effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Before deciding <strong>on</strong> the most appropriate regulatory resp<strong>on</strong>se, any specific industry<br />

problems and objectives need to be clearly defined. Once the decisi<strong>on</strong> has been made<br />

that interventi<strong>on</strong> is necessary then the focus can properly shift to choosing the most<br />

appropriate model of regulati<strong>on</strong> to achieve the desired outcome.<br />

In a broad sense, regulati<strong>on</strong> can be c<strong>on</strong>sidered as a spectrum ranging from<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> where there is little or no government involvement, through<br />

quasi-regulati<strong>on</strong> which refers to a range of rules, instruments or standards that<br />

government expects businesses to comply with, to explicit government regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Australia is at the forefr<strong>on</strong>t of internati<strong>on</strong>al policy initiatives to promote regulatory<br />

reform and effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has had regard to the<br />

internati<strong>on</strong>al experience with industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> and an outline of internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

policy and practice is included in this <strong>Report</strong> as Appendix D.<br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulatory schemes tend to promote good practice and target specific problems<br />

within industries, impose lower compliance costs <strong>on</strong> business, and offer quick, low<br />

cost dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> procedures. Effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can also avoid the often<br />

overly prescriptive nature of regulati<strong>on</strong> and allow industry the flexibility to provide<br />

greater choice for c<strong>on</strong>sumers and to be more resp<strong>on</strong>sive to changing c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

expectati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> includes a host of opti<strong>on</strong>s ranging from a simple code of ethics, to<br />

codes that are drafted with legislative precisi<strong>on</strong> together with sophisticated customer<br />

dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has examined self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in terms of improved market outcomes<br />

for c<strong>on</strong>sumers with direct reference to lowering costs to industry participants, thus<br />

providing shared benefits to both businesses and c<strong>on</strong>sumers. This approach focuses<br />

<strong>on</strong> the efficiency and effectiveness of self-regulatory structures. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has<br />

assessed that there needs to be a balance between minimising costs for business and<br />

the benefits to both business and c<strong>on</strong>sumers by looking at the market circumstances<br />

where self-regulati<strong>on</strong> arose.<br />

1


Good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> involves applying an appropriate scheme to a<br />

specific market failure or social policy objective. Ascertaining which scheme should<br />

be applied will depend <strong>on</strong> the nature and risk of the market failure and the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences of no acti<strong>on</strong>. In other words, there is no <strong>on</strong>e model for self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

N<strong>on</strong>etheless, it is possible to identify comm<strong>on</strong> characteristics of successful schemes<br />

and the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has d<strong>on</strong>e so in Chapter 6 of its <strong>Report</strong>.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has applied these principles when inquiring into and reporting <strong>on</strong> its<br />

Terms of Reference. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has reached the following c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s which are<br />

cross-referenced to the body of the <strong>Report</strong> to assist readers to locate the discussi<strong>on</strong> of,<br />

and rati<strong>on</strong>ale for, each finding.<br />

Chapter 3: Types of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets in Australia<br />

There are different reas<strong>on</strong>s for establishing self-regulatory schemes. Industries may<br />

self-regulate to improve the image of suppliers or to promote c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence<br />

in new products or technologies. Industries may also self-regulate to avoid<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong>, satisfy legislative requirements or minimise costly litigati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> has an array of self-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>s available to address specific<br />

problems and objectives, including codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct, industry service charters,<br />

guidelines and standards, as well as industry-based accreditati<strong>on</strong> and complaint<br />

handling schemes.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> examined self-regulati<strong>on</strong> across a broad range of industries, including<br />

broadcasting and media, telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s, and financial services. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

also examined many self-regulatory schemes dealing with marketing practices<br />

generally – including advertising, direct marketing and the use of scanning<br />

equipment in supermarkets.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> reached the following c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s:<br />

1. There is a broad and diverse range of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> at the nati<strong>on</strong>al level<br />

affecting c<strong>on</strong>sumers (page 20).<br />

2. There is no single model for industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> as it depends <strong>on</strong> what is<br />

trying to be achieved (page 20).<br />

Chapter 4: Gaps and overlaps in the coverage of self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulatory schemes operate in dynamic markets, which are influenced by<br />

globalisati<strong>on</strong>, increasing vertical integrati<strong>on</strong>, and the growth of ‘hybrid’ products<br />

that span traditi<strong>on</strong>al markets or industries.<br />

As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence, gaps and overlaps can emerge in the coverage of various<br />

products, services, sectors and industries. Similarly, existing self-regulatory schemes<br />

may find themselves covering the same ground where the distincti<strong>on</strong> between<br />

products or services has become blurred.<br />

2


It is undesirable that there be market problems that are not addressed by industry<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, as c<strong>on</strong>sumers may find it costly and time c<strong>on</strong>suming to obtain<br />

redress through the Courts. It is equally undesirable that there be inefficient<br />

duplicati<strong>on</strong> of self-regulatory schemes. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> is c<strong>on</strong>fident that self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

is sufficiently flexible to resp<strong>on</strong>d quickly to new market issues.<br />

In short, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>cluded that:<br />

3. Gaps and overlaps c<strong>on</strong>tinually emerge and re-emerge in dynamic markets<br />

(page 30).<br />

4. A ‘gap’ in the market does not necessarily mean that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the<br />

appropriate soluti<strong>on</strong> (page 31).<br />

5. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is a flexible resp<strong>on</strong>se to market failure and may fill a ‘gap’<br />

quickly and efficiently (page 31).<br />

6. Some small businesses can have difficulties in participating in self-regulatory<br />

schemes as can c<strong>on</strong>sumers (page 32).<br />

Chapter 5: <strong>Industry</strong> envir<strong>on</strong>ment and market circumstances where<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be most effective<br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is not the answer to every market failure and all social policy<br />

objectives. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> was asked to provide some guidance for industry and<br />

policymakers as to where self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to prove most effective.<br />

There is a general recogniti<strong>on</strong> that industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is often more flexible and<br />

less costly for both business and c<strong>on</strong>sumers than direct government involvement.<br />

However, it is necessary to ensure that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the appropriate form of<br />

interventi<strong>on</strong> given the particular industry envir<strong>on</strong>ment and market circumstances.<br />

The circumstances where self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be most effective will depend <strong>on</strong><br />

the nature and extent of market failure, the market structure, industry and c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

interests.<br />

Nature and extent of market failure<br />

7. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be most effective where there are clearly defined<br />

problems but no high risk of serious or widespread harm to c<strong>on</strong>sumers<br />

(page 42).<br />

Market structure<br />

8. An industry envir<strong>on</strong>ment with an active industry associati<strong>on</strong> and/or industry<br />

cohesiveness is most likely to administer effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> as industry<br />

participants are more likely to commit financial resources, c<strong>on</strong>sult with<br />

stakeholders and m<strong>on</strong>itor the effectiveness of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> (page 43).<br />

3


9. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is less effective where there is a broad spread of smaller<br />

businesses that do not communicate with each other (page 44).<br />

10. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is most likely to be effective in a competitive market as industry<br />

participants are more likely to be committed to it, either to differentiate their<br />

products, or in fear of losing market share (page 45).<br />

11. A more mature industry may be able to administer more effective<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, as industry participants are more likely to have sufficient<br />

resources and be more committed while any ‘shakeout’ of rogue traders will<br />

already have occurred (page 47).<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>sumer interests<br />

12. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be most effective where firms recognise that their<br />

future viability depends not <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong> their relati<strong>on</strong>ship with their current<br />

customers and shareholders, but also <strong>on</strong> the wider community (page 47).<br />

13. The more incentives there are for industry participants to initiate and comply<br />

with self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, then the more chance a scheme can remedy specific<br />

industry problems (page 48).<br />

14. The extent to which industry participants are prepared to sign up to a<br />

self-regulatory scheme will affect the ability of that scheme to provide effective<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. Where a scheme has a high level of c<strong>on</strong>sumer recogniti<strong>on</strong>, to the<br />

point where c<strong>on</strong>sumers will favour scheme participants when making<br />

purchasing decisi<strong>on</strong>s, then the scheme is most likely to be effective. This will<br />

create incentives for n<strong>on</strong>-members to join the scheme (page 51).<br />

15. Where there are cost advantages and/or increased flexibility in self-regulatory<br />

initiatives to address specific industry problems compared with government<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> or the court system, then there is a greater chance of improving<br />

market outcomes for both business and c<strong>on</strong>sumers, and minimising compliance<br />

costs for businesses (page 53).<br />

Chapter 6: Good practice and cost-effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> methods<br />

There is no single ‘best practice’ model for self-regulati<strong>on</strong> because a successful model<br />

needs to be designed to address particular problems identified in the c<strong>on</strong>text of<br />

particular market circumstances. Accordingly, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sidered it<br />

inappropriate to develop a ‘checklist’ of features of good self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

N<strong>on</strong>etheless, it is possible to identify critical elements that, individually or<br />

collectively, have underpinned effective schemes.<br />

Good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can be understood as improving market outcomes<br />

for c<strong>on</strong>sumers at the lowest cost to businesses, and the following factors were seen as<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tributing to this.<br />

4


C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong><br />

16. C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> between industry, c<strong>on</strong>sumers and Government can help ensure<br />

that specific problems and social policy objectives can be identified and<br />

addressed (page 58).<br />

Coverage and publicity<br />

17. Increased industry coverage of schemes ensures that the benefits from<br />

standards of practice in schemes flow to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. Wide coverage also<br />

ensures that c<strong>on</strong>sumers can identify self-regulatory schemes (page 61).<br />

18. Clarity in the schemes’ documentati<strong>on</strong> can help industry understand their<br />

obligati<strong>on</strong>s and assist dispute schemes interpret legal rights. Clarity can also<br />

help c<strong>on</strong>sumers understand their rights (page 61).<br />

19. C<strong>on</strong>sumer awareness of schemes ensures that c<strong>on</strong>sumers understand their<br />

rights and reap the benefits from standards of practice set by schemes. Schemes<br />

are encouraged to make use of new technologies such as the Internet, by<br />

making complaints cost free to the c<strong>on</strong>sumer, through writing sample letters of<br />

complaint, through taking oral complaints where possible, and through<br />

transferring complainants between schemes where possible (page 62).<br />

20. <strong>Industry</strong> awareness of schemes is needed to make sure industry participants<br />

understand their obligati<strong>on</strong>s and, where appropriate, understand the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences of failing to abide by these obligati<strong>on</strong>s (page 64).<br />

Administrati<strong>on</strong><br />

21. A good administrative body can identify issues, collect data, m<strong>on</strong>itor the<br />

scheme, enhance credibility and ensure compliance costs are at an effective<br />

minimum level (page 64).<br />

22. Data collecti<strong>on</strong> by an industry scheme is a valuable tool in identifying systemic<br />

issues and allows industry to address these problems, which in turn, can<br />

improve market outcomes for both businesses and c<strong>on</strong>sumers (page 65).<br />

23. As c<strong>on</strong>sumers cannot guard against specific industry problems that they do not<br />

know exist, transparency in schemes is an important mechanism to ensure<br />

credibility and accountability (page 66).<br />

Dispute procedures and sancti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

24. <strong>Industry</strong> adherence to self-regulatory schemes is essential to ensure that the<br />

benefits flowing from the standards of practice set by schemes are passed <strong>on</strong>to<br />

the c<strong>on</strong>sumer (page 67).<br />

5


25. Where the standard of c<strong>on</strong>duct has been breached, self-regulatory schemes<br />

should incorporate complaint handling and dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms to<br />

provide appropriate redress to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. The appropriate redress mechanism<br />

will depend <strong>on</strong> the nature of the specific problem and the c<strong>on</strong>sequences of<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-compliance (page 68).<br />

26. A range of sancti<strong>on</strong>s can be used by industry in order to achieve compliance<br />

depending <strong>on</strong> the nature of the specific problem and c<strong>on</strong>sequences of<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-compliance. The severity of the sancti<strong>on</strong> should depend <strong>on</strong> the seriousness<br />

of the breach (page 70).<br />

27. <strong>Industry</strong> needs to manage the risk of any anti-competitive practices in schemes,<br />

particularly where sancti<strong>on</strong>s are involved (page 72).<br />

M<strong>on</strong>itoring and reviewing<br />

28. M<strong>on</strong>itoring of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is essential to ensure that it is still relevant to the<br />

industry addressing specific problems and improving market outcomes. In this<br />

c<strong>on</strong>text, reviews and annual reporting are useful tools for m<strong>on</strong>itoring schemes<br />

and can also assist in the transparency and accountability of schemes.<br />

Preferably, reviews should be periodic, independent and the results made<br />

publicly available (page 73).<br />

Cost-effectiveness<br />

29. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> comes at a cost, in administrati<strong>on</strong>, promoti<strong>on</strong> and compliance.<br />

However, self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can be cheaper (in terms of compliance costs) and<br />

more flexible than Government regulati<strong>on</strong> and the court system. Ultimately, the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer bears the cost of regulati<strong>on</strong> in most cases (page 75).<br />

30. Any funding arrangement for self-regulati<strong>on</strong> should be transparent and<br />

designed so as not to put businesses at a competitive disadvantage through<br />

excessive compliance costs (page 79).<br />

Chapter 7: Approaches to promoting and coordinating industry<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

There are a variety of opti<strong>on</strong>s for designing and promoting self-regulatory schemes<br />

and what works for <strong>on</strong>e industry may not work for another. It follows that the ‘mix’<br />

of industry, government and c<strong>on</strong>sumer involvement that works well for <strong>on</strong>e<br />

self-regulatory scheme may be inappropriate for another.<br />

6


<strong>Industry</strong> approaches to promoting self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

31. Experience has shown that industry will initiate a self-regulatory scheme in<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>se to a clear commercial imperative to win c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence and<br />

boost sales (page 85).<br />

32. <strong>Industry</strong> may promote self-regulati<strong>on</strong> as an alternative to government<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> where there is perceived to be a serious market failure or important<br />

social policy objective (page 85).<br />

Role of government in promoting and coordinating self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

33. Government involvement in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is justified when there is a public<br />

policy objective that would otherwise call for a regulatory resp<strong>on</strong>se (page 87).<br />

34. Government can assist in analysing systemic problems in an industry and in<br />

facilitating the design of a self-regulatory resp<strong>on</strong>se to address those systemic<br />

problems (page 93).<br />

35. The degree of government involvement will depend <strong>on</strong> the significance of the<br />

market failure or social policy objective being addressed and the c<strong>on</strong>sequences<br />

of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> proving ineffective (page 93).<br />

36. Government can assist in integrating schemes into the regulatory framework<br />

(page 91).<br />

37. Government is uniquely placed to promote internati<strong>on</strong>al cooperati<strong>on</strong> and<br />

harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of self-regulatory initiatives (page 91).<br />

Role of c<strong>on</strong>sumer advocates in promoting self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

38. C<strong>on</strong>sumer input is important in the development and in maintaining the<br />

relevance of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>sumer advocates can promote c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

c<strong>on</strong>fidence in self-regulatory schemes (page 98).<br />

39. C<strong>on</strong>sumer participati<strong>on</strong> will be limited by human and financial resource<br />

c<strong>on</strong>straints if there is no external financial assistance forthcoming (page 98).<br />

Other c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

40. Code administrati<strong>on</strong> authorities established by industry should take<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for the m<strong>on</strong>itoring and review of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, in c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong><br />

with government and c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups.<br />

Chapter 8: Opti<strong>on</strong>s that facilitate the improvement and harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes<br />

Effective dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> is a crucial element of industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> offering<br />

redress to c<strong>on</strong>sumers and it can also identify systemic problems in the industry.<br />

Dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes are an excellent m<strong>on</strong>itoring tool increasing performance<br />

and industry standards.<br />

7


41. In the future dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes may operate across different sectors<br />

with similar products/services, driven by changes in technology and market<br />

circumstances. Harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of schemes would be less costly and c<strong>on</strong>fusing to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers and the use of umbrella-type arrangements with a single<br />

co-ordinated access point would likewise be of assistance to c<strong>on</strong>sumers (page<br />

106).<br />

42. Promoti<strong>on</strong> of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes to c<strong>on</strong>sumers raises their awareness of<br />

the availability of quick and inexpensive redress (page 109).<br />

8


Chapter 1<br />

Introducti<strong>on</strong><br />

On 12 August 1999, the Minister for Financial Services & Regulati<strong>on</strong>, the<br />

H<strong>on</strong> Joe Hockey MP, who is also the Minister with resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for C<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

Affairs, established an independent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> to advise him <strong>on</strong> a range of issues<br />

regarding industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in Australia.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> members to undertake this inquiry were drawn mainly from the<br />

private sector, with the emphasis placed <strong>on</strong> representati<strong>on</strong> from key stakeholders,<br />

with knowledge of, and involvement in, self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Inquiry process<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> met for the first time <strong>on</strong> 30 September 1999, to discuss the format and<br />

directi<strong>on</strong> of the inquiry. One of the most important objectives of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> was to<br />

ensure all stakeholders had ample opportunity to c<strong>on</strong>tribute to the inquiry. The<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sidered that c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s with stakeholders across industry, business,<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers groups and government were imperative to explore a variety of<br />

experiences in the field and generate an informed and comprehensive report.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> agreed that the first step to achieving effective c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> was<br />

authorising the release of the Issues Paper. 1 The purpose of this Issues Paper was to<br />

provide informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the scope of the Terms of Reference and the inquiry<br />

methodology to assist stakeholders in preparing submissi<strong>on</strong>s to the inquiry. The call<br />

for submissi<strong>on</strong>s was advertised nati<strong>on</strong>ally <strong>on</strong> Friday, 15 October 1999 (the <strong>Australian</strong><br />

Financial Review) and in The <strong>Australian</strong> and major metropolitan dailies in each State<br />

and Territory <strong>on</strong> the weekend of 16 October 1999.<br />

To supplement this nati<strong>on</strong>al advertising campaign, the Chair of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> wrote<br />

to a wide range of industry, c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups and government agencies (over 80<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>s) likely to have an interest in the inquiry, inviting then to make a<br />

submissi<strong>on</strong> and attend c<strong>on</strong>sultative meetings with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g>. In additi<strong>on</strong>, other<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>s, including the Council of Small Business Organisati<strong>on</strong>s of Australia<br />

and the <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Forum, widely distributed the<br />

Issues Paper to interested parties to ensure thorough saturati<strong>on</strong> across Australia.<br />

1 The Issues Paper can be found at www.treasury.gov.au/self-regtaskforce.<br />

9


Regi<strong>on</strong>al Australia was also targeted with <strong>on</strong>e-page fliers, prepared by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g>,<br />

for distributi<strong>on</strong> to country areas with assistance from the Business and Professi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

Women of Australia. Letters were also sent to all regi<strong>on</strong>al development councils<br />

around Australia inviting them to participate in the inquiry through encouraging<br />

submissi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> issues such as access to self-regulatory schemes for regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers and industry. A number of regi<strong>on</strong>al development councils took up the<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s offer to receive a copy of the draft report with a view to possibly<br />

participating in the sec<strong>on</strong>d round of c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong> to this media and promoti<strong>on</strong>al campaign, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> set up its own<br />

webpage <strong>on</strong> the Treasury site (http://www.treasury.gov.au/self-regtaskforce) and<br />

electr<strong>on</strong>ic letterbox for lodgement of submissi<strong>on</strong>s and queries<br />

(selfregtaskforce@treasury.gov.au). Links were also established to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

webpage from other sites that stakeholders were likely to visit. The Issues Paper was<br />

published <strong>on</strong> the website, together with reference documents such as the Codes Policy<br />

Framework and Grey-letter Law.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> was pleased at the numerous resp<strong>on</strong>ses elicited from stakeholders<br />

throughout the inquiry. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> received over 40 submissi<strong>on</strong>s (listed at<br />

Appendix A) which are used extensively within the body of the <strong>Report</strong>.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong> to calling for submissi<strong>on</strong>s, the first round of c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s was<br />

undertaken during November and December 1999 and March 2000. Public<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s were held with industry, business, c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups and government<br />

agencies located in Canberra, Melbourne and Sydney. The c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s were<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ducted in a variety of formats with a number of individual and roundtable<br />

discussi<strong>on</strong>s held. A list of organisati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>sulted during the inquiry is listed at<br />

Appendix B.<br />

The sec<strong>on</strong>d meeting of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> was held <strong>on</strong> 14 December 1999. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

reviewed the inquiry process to date and was enthused by the resp<strong>on</strong>se received by<br />

stakeholders. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> examined the trends of informati<strong>on</strong> received. The<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> was also c<strong>on</strong>cerned at the short timeframe attributed to the inquiry<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sidering the large amount of work that was still required to be undertaken. The<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> was anxious to avoid shortening the public c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> period due to a<br />

lack of time. Hence, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> applied to the Minister for a three m<strong>on</strong>th extensi<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>on</strong> the reporting date. The Minister granted this extensi<strong>on</strong>. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> also<br />

commissi<strong>on</strong>ed a number of special research tasks to further investigate the Terms of<br />

Reference.<br />

The importance placed <strong>on</strong> a comprehensive and thorough analysis of market<br />

circumstances where industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> was likely to be most and least<br />

effective, became the catalyst for the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> to engage a c<strong>on</strong>sultant. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

required the c<strong>on</strong>sultant to structure its research around case studies where industry<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> had been implemented. As part of its research strategy, the c<strong>on</strong>sultant<br />

met with stakeholders in each of the identified industries to gain a comprehensive<br />

insight into the market. The aim of this research was not to identify self-regulatory<br />

10


success and failure in particular industries but to more broadly identify the<br />

characteristics of the envir<strong>on</strong>ment and market that have influenced the effectiveness<br />

of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. This report is to be published <strong>on</strong> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s webpage.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> was also keen to research the changing regulatory envir<strong>on</strong>ment within<br />

the internati<strong>on</strong>al arena, with special attenti<strong>on</strong> to be given to developments in<br />

industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. To ensure Australia could potentially learn from this<br />

research, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> supported the need to focus <strong>on</strong> governments that had already<br />

implemented some form of industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> policy. The Secretariat to the<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> undertook this research with the view to investigate current issues and<br />

trends in the internati<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> Secretariat subscribed to an internati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>on</strong>-line forum <strong>on</strong><br />

voluntary codes, hosted by the Canadian Office of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs. The members<br />

of this forum come from a wide variety of government and n<strong>on</strong>-government<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>s throughout the world and provide invaluable informati<strong>on</strong>, networks<br />

and links to self-regulatory practices and voluntary codes in operati<strong>on</strong>. The Terms of<br />

Reference of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> inquiry were posted <strong>on</strong> this forum and c<strong>on</strong>sequently<br />

generated a large amount of interest. The numerous replies provided valuable<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> self-regulatory practices, from a variety of internati<strong>on</strong>al governments,<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>s and individuals. The internati<strong>on</strong>al work can be found at Appendix D.<br />

Structure of report<br />

The main body of the report addresses the six broad issues that the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> was<br />

asked to inquire and report <strong>on</strong>.<br />

In particular, chapter 2 sets out the framework for the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> inquiry and<br />

discusses the steps involved in assessing whether self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the most<br />

appropriate tool.<br />

Chapter 3 discusses the reas<strong>on</strong>s for the initiati<strong>on</strong> of self-regulatory schemes and the<br />

spectrum of schemes in Australia ranging from guidelines to more sophisticated<br />

codes of practice. The directory of self-regulatory schemes also lists a host of<br />

self-regulatory schemes operating at the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth level in c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets. 2<br />

Chapter 4 then discusses gaps and overlaps in the coverage of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. There<br />

has been c<strong>on</strong>siderable growth in the number of self-regulatory schemes across many<br />

industries. In additi<strong>on</strong>, these self-regulatory schemes operate in dynamic markets,<br />

which are influenced by globalisati<strong>on</strong>, increasing vertical integrati<strong>on</strong>, and the growth<br />

of ‘hybrid’ products that span traditi<strong>on</strong>al markets or industries. As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence,<br />

gaps and overlaps can emerge in the coverage of various products, services, sectors<br />

and industries.<br />

2 The directory of self-regulatory schemes can be found at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s website.<br />

11


Chapter 5 maps out the industry envir<strong>on</strong>ment and market circumstances where<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be most effective. It is necessary to ensure that<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the appropriate form of interventi<strong>on</strong> given particular industry<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment and market circumstances, otherwise inappropriate interventi<strong>on</strong> could<br />

create new problems. As discussed above, the c<strong>on</strong>sultant’s report also analyses the<br />

circumstances where industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be most and least effective.<br />

Chapter 6 discusses good practice and cost-effective self-regulatory methods. Good<br />

practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can be understood as improving market outcomes for both<br />

business and c<strong>on</strong>sumers at the lowest cost to businesses. A particular self-regulatory<br />

scheme may not be appropriate in circumstances where other forms of regulati<strong>on</strong> are<br />

able to provide better outcomes at a lower cost.<br />

Chapter 7 then discusses approaches to promote and co-ordinate self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. The<br />

roles of industry, government and c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups are dynamic, adapting to the<br />

changing face of the <strong>Australian</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy and, in particular, resp<strong>on</strong>ding to<br />

competitive pressures, regulatory reform, new technologies and the increasing<br />

globalisati<strong>on</strong> of c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets. This chapter first examines the role that industry<br />

has played in promoting and coordinating self-regulatory schemes. It then discusses<br />

the role of Government as a stakeholder, developer, promoter, m<strong>on</strong>itor and enforcer<br />

of schemes, as well as the crucial role that c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups have played and will<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tinue to play in the development of industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. Finally, the chapter<br />

analyses a number of opti<strong>on</strong>s to better co-ordinate and promote self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

including discussi<strong>on</strong> of whether a centralised Government agency, an oversight<br />

committee, or model codes would be appropriate. Appendix C also discusses where<br />

codes are underpinned in legislati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Finally, chapter 8 discusses opti<strong>on</strong>s to facilitate the improvement and harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong><br />

of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes. Effective dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> is a crucial element of<br />

industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> offering redress to c<strong>on</strong>sumers and it can also identify<br />

systemic problems in the industry. However, dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes come at a<br />

cost. In particular, they can be costly for small industry groups.<br />

12


Chapter 2<br />

Framework for the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> Inquiry<br />

At the outset of the inquiry, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sidered the approach it would take to<br />

examining the matters under reference. The scope of the Terms of Reference and the<br />

inquiry methodology the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> intended to adopt were set out in the Issues Paper<br />

released in October 1999.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> was established to advise the Government <strong>on</strong> promoting effective<br />

industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> inquiry is occurring in the c<strong>on</strong>text of the<br />

Government’s overarching policy <strong>on</strong> ‘making markets work’ for the shared benefit of<br />

business and c<strong>on</strong>sumers. In this c<strong>on</strong>text, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has defined effective industry<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> as industry initiatives that improve market outcomes for c<strong>on</strong>sumers<br />

while reducing compliance costs for business.<br />

Onerous compliance burdens are recognised as detrimental to business. What is less<br />

obvious but equally important is that c<strong>on</strong>sumers may also ‘pay’ for sophisticated and<br />

costly industry self-regulatory schemes — notably in the form of higher prices.<br />

Moreover, industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can also have the purpose or effect of inhibiting<br />

competiti<strong>on</strong> — with serious implicati<strong>on</strong>s for c<strong>on</strong>sumers. 3<br />

It follows that c<strong>on</strong>sumers and businesses have a mutual interest in finding simple<br />

and inexpensive mechanisms for resolving market problems.<br />

Principles<br />

¾ The appropriate form of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> will depend <strong>on</strong> what is trying to be<br />

achieved ⎯ that is the way in which it is necessary to improve market outcomes<br />

for c<strong>on</strong>sumers. This can vary within and between industries.<br />

¾ The form of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> adopted by industry should be the <strong>on</strong>e which<br />

effectively solves the identified problem and minimises costs for industry.<br />

3 <strong>Industry</strong> self-regulatory schemes that inhibit competiti<strong>on</strong> are at risk of breaching the restrictive<br />

trade practices provisi<strong>on</strong>s of the Trade Practices Act 1974. The <strong>Australian</strong> Competiti<strong>on</strong> and<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Commissi<strong>on</strong> (ACCC) has the power to authorise such schemes <strong>on</strong> public benefit<br />

grounds, giving the schemes immunity from court acti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Details of the ACCC authorisati<strong>on</strong> process are available from the ACCC website at:<br />

http://www.accc.gov.au/adjudicati<strong>on</strong>/fs-adjudicate.htm.<br />

13


Analytical tools for identifying lowest cost-effective opti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Internati<strong>on</strong>ally, and also in Australia, in line with the drive for efficiency gains, there<br />

has been an increasing focus <strong>on</strong> regulatory reform.<br />

Many of the analytical tools that have been developed to ensure effective regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

by governments can be adapted easily to ensure effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> by industry,<br />

and some of these are discussed below.<br />

The Council of <strong>Australian</strong> Governments has issued Principles and Guidelines for<br />

Nati<strong>on</strong>al Standard Setting and Regulatory Acti<strong>on</strong>. 4 While these guidelines were framed<br />

for proposed regulatory acti<strong>on</strong> by governments, the general principles apply equally<br />

to industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. Under the COAG Guidelines, the impact of proposed<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> must be assessed to ascertain that regulati<strong>on</strong> is necessary, and if so, what<br />

is the most efficient regulatory approach to use. This assessment should c<strong>on</strong>sider:<br />

¾ the objective;<br />

¾ a c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> of alternative approaches;<br />

¾ the impact <strong>on</strong> affected groups of proposed approaches;<br />

¾ a cost/benefit analysis;<br />

¾ c<strong>on</strong>sistency or any proposed approach with internati<strong>on</strong>al standards; and<br />

¾ mechanisms for reviewing the proposed regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The opti<strong>on</strong> of no acti<strong>on</strong> should be c<strong>on</strong>sidered if it will produce the best outcome for<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers and industry. This opti<strong>on</strong> is worth pursuing if a self-regulatory scheme<br />

cannot prove that it will improve the situati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Similarly, the guidelines prepared by the Office of Regulati<strong>on</strong> Review to assist<br />

Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth agencies to prepare Regulati<strong>on</strong> Impact Statements (RIS), offered the<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> an attractive analytical framework for assessing the effectiveness of<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. 5 The RIS Guidelines also require identificati<strong>on</strong> of the problem being<br />

addressed, specificati<strong>on</strong> of the desired objective(s), identificati<strong>on</strong> of opti<strong>on</strong>s and an<br />

assessment of the costs and benefits of each opti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

4 Council of <strong>Australian</strong> Governments (COAG) endorsed by COAG in April 1995 and amended in<br />

November 1997, Principles and Guidelines for Nati<strong>on</strong>al Standard Setting and Regulatory Acti<strong>on</strong> by<br />

Ministerial Councils and Standard-Setting Bodies. This document is available from the Department<br />

of the Prime Minister and Cabinet, including <strong>on</strong> the Departmental website at:<br />

http://www.pmc.gov.au/briefing/doc/coagpg.pdf.<br />

5 Office of Regulati<strong>on</strong> Review 1998, A Guide to Regulati<strong>on</strong>, Sec<strong>on</strong>d Editi<strong>on</strong>. Available <strong>on</strong> the<br />

Internet at http://www.pc.gov.au/orr/reguide2/index.html.<br />

14


Catalysts for industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>Industry</strong> self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is increasingly being seen as an alternative means of<br />

promoting fair trading, ethical c<strong>on</strong>duct and streamlining compliance with agreed<br />

product and service standards in an industry. While industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can<br />

advance c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence in products and individual companies, it also can<br />

promote good business practices.<br />

The Government is encouraging self-regulati<strong>on</strong> because this mechanism is often<br />

more flexible and less costly for both business and c<strong>on</strong>sumers than direct<br />

government regulati<strong>on</strong>. In the Government resp<strong>on</strong>se to the report of the Small<br />

Business Deregulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g>, it was made clear that:<br />

The Government is keen for industry to take ownership and resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for developing<br />

effective and efficient self-regulatory mechanisms where this is appropriate. 6<br />

Properly c<strong>on</strong>ceived and drafted, industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can be a positive tool for<br />

industry and a safeguard for c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

It is generally accepted that well functi<strong>on</strong>ing markets produce better results for the<br />

community. Competiti<strong>on</strong> results in greater choice and lower prices for c<strong>on</strong>sumers<br />

and efficient resource allocati<strong>on</strong> towards more successful suppliers.<br />

Generally with clear informati<strong>on</strong> flows, markets provide incentives for business and<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers to resolve many of the problems without interventi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

However, markets can ‘fail’ to deliver the optimal efficient allocati<strong>on</strong> of resources in<br />

the ec<strong>on</strong>omy for reas<strong>on</strong>s, including the following.<br />

¾ The market is characterised by imperfect competiti<strong>on</strong>;<br />

¾ There is insufficient informati<strong>on</strong> available to c<strong>on</strong>sumers to allow them to make<br />

informed choices; 7 and/or<br />

6 Statement by the Prime Minister, the H<strong>on</strong> John Howard MP 24 March 1997, More Time for<br />

Business. Available <strong>on</strong> the Internet at:<br />

http://www.dewrsb.gov.au/group_osb/smallbus/moretime.htm.<br />

7 This form of market failure is typically referred to as ‘informati<strong>on</strong> asymmetry’ since there is an<br />

imbalance in the informati<strong>on</strong> available to suppliers and c<strong>on</strong>sumers. This does not necessarily<br />

imply that suppliers have 'withheld' informati<strong>on</strong> that c<strong>on</strong>sumers need to make decisi<strong>on</strong>s; it may<br />

result from the complexity of the transacti<strong>on</strong>s involved and the expertise required to<br />

understand all aspects of such transacti<strong>on</strong>s. N<strong>on</strong>etheless, informati<strong>on</strong> asymmetries are often<br />

remedied by improved informati<strong>on</strong> disclosure to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. The various forms of market<br />

failure are addressed in the Codes of C<strong>on</strong>duct Policy Framework released by the then Minister for<br />

Customs and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs in March 1998; this document is available <strong>on</strong> the Internet at<br />

http://www.treasury.gov.au (choose C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs/Publicati<strong>on</strong>s/<strong>Industry</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-Regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

Publicati<strong>on</strong>s).<br />

15


¾ There are high transacti<strong>on</strong> costs for c<strong>on</strong>sumers. 8<br />

In such circumstances, there is often an incentive for industries to self-regulate.<br />

Markets may also fail to fulfil significant social policy objectives, with the result that<br />

the relevant industry may face a choice between government interventi<strong>on</strong> or<br />

industry-based initiatives to ensure the market delivers results c<strong>on</strong>sistent with those<br />

desired by the community.<br />

When industry is c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>ted with the dem<strong>on</strong>strated failure of the market mechanism<br />

to deliver a problem in the marketplace, the nature and magnitude of that problem<br />

must be accurately assessed. Failure to understand the problem may lead to an<br />

inappropriate soluti<strong>on</strong> being used. Such an outcome may have unintended<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences for many sectors of the community.<br />

Identifying and quantifying the problem<br />

The types of factors that need to be c<strong>on</strong>sidered include:<br />

¾ the causes of the problem;<br />

¾ who is affected;<br />

¾ the c<strong>on</strong>sequences of the problem for the people affected and the wider<br />

community;<br />

¾ who benefits from the situati<strong>on</strong> and to what extent;<br />

¾ the scale of the problem; and<br />

¾ whether it is local, state, nati<strong>on</strong>al or internati<strong>on</strong>al.<br />

The presence of market failure or absence of socially desirable outcomes may not be<br />

sufficient to justify industry setting up a self-regulatory regime. Inappropriate<br />

interventi<strong>on</strong> could create new problems that are greater than the problems it was<br />

designed to fix. In particular, a self-regulatory scheme may have an incidental<br />

anti-competitive effect, the impact of which is more damaging to c<strong>on</strong>sumers than the<br />

original market problem.<br />

For this reas<strong>on</strong>, any interventi<strong>on</strong> needs to be weighed up to ascertain whether the<br />

extent of the problem is sufficient to justify interventi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> believes that the specific problem and objectives need to be clearly<br />

defined before any decisi<strong>on</strong> is made about how the desired outcome is to be<br />

achieved. Once the decisi<strong>on</strong> has been made that interventi<strong>on</strong> is necessary then the<br />

8 High transacti<strong>on</strong> costs refer to the costs of participating in a market and include the costs of<br />

searching for relevant informati<strong>on</strong> and the costs of obtaining redress if a supplier fails to h<strong>on</strong>our<br />

its side of the bargain.<br />

16


focus can properly shift to choosing the most appropriate model of regulati<strong>on</strong> to<br />

achieve the desired outcome.<br />

Choosing the appropriate soluti<strong>on</strong> from the spectrum of<br />

self-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

In a broad sense, regulati<strong>on</strong> can be c<strong>on</strong>sidered as a spectrum ranging from<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> where there is little or no government involvement, to<br />

quasi-regulati<strong>on</strong> which refers to a range of rules, instruments or standards that<br />

government expects businesses to comply with, through to explicit government<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong>. Similarly, there is a spectrum of self-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>s to address market<br />

failure and social policy objectives and the art of developing effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

is to ‘customise’ soluti<strong>on</strong>s to provide optimal outcomes.<br />

The spectrum of self-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>s available to industry is a c<strong>on</strong>tinuum.<br />

Towards the least costly, least interventi<strong>on</strong>ist end of the spectrum are industry<br />

agreements to improve the disclosure of informati<strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. Such initiatives<br />

may involve voluntary disclosure standards or guidelines. Such initiatives address<br />

market failure that is due to c<strong>on</strong>sumers making poor choices <strong>on</strong> the basis of<br />

insufficient informati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

¾ Somewhere <strong>on</strong> the c<strong>on</strong>tinuum are self-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>s like customer service<br />

charters (that provide informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> respective rights and obligati<strong>on</strong>s) and<br />

voluntary industry codes that provide guidance for members but do not<br />

m<strong>on</strong>itor or enforce compliance.<br />

- Such initiatives may be effective in addressing market failure provided<br />

there are commercial incentives for industry participants to comply (or at<br />

least an absence of commercial imperatives for industry participants to<br />

rely <strong>on</strong> the market failure).<br />

¾ At the most interventi<strong>on</strong>ist end of the spectrum are industry self-regulatory<br />

schemes that basically mirror regulati<strong>on</strong> in that they incorporate industry codes<br />

drafted like legislative provisi<strong>on</strong>s, mechanisms to ensure compliance by all<br />

industry participants, and redress mechanisms to resolve customer disputes.<br />

It is a basic principle of industry efficiency and public welfare that the degree of<br />

interventi<strong>on</strong> should be the minimum necessary to achieve the identified objectives.<br />

The manner of interventi<strong>on</strong> should be that which imposes the least cost of<br />

compliance c<strong>on</strong>sistent with achieving the identified objectives.<br />

17


The advantages of industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to address market<br />

failure<br />

As discussed in the Grey-letter Law report (1997), self-regulatory approaches can<br />

effectively remedy market problems, but can be as inefficient as any form of<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> if they do not address the underlying problem. 9 <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is a means<br />

to an end, it is not an end in itself.<br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is a viable opti<strong>on</strong> if it can improve market outcomes with direct<br />

reference to lowering costs to industry participants and providing benefits to both<br />

businesses and c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulatory schemes tend to promote good practice and target specific problems<br />

within industries, impose lower compliance costs <strong>on</strong> business, and offer quick, low<br />

cost dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> procedures. Effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can also avoid the often<br />

overly prescriptive nature of regulati<strong>on</strong> and allow industry the flexibility to provide<br />

greater choice for c<strong>on</strong>sumers and to be more resp<strong>on</strong>sive to changing c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

expectati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Specific problems can be addressed <strong>on</strong> an industry wide basis, and so enhance the<br />

competitive process. However, it is also necessary to minimise the anti-competitive<br />

potential of industry self-regulatory schemes by ensuring that such schemes do not<br />

set up barriers to entry to the industry, nor stifle innovati<strong>on</strong> or competiti<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>gst<br />

industry participants. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> may not be appropriate in circumstances where<br />

other forms of regulati<strong>on</strong> are able to provide more cost-effective outcomes.<br />

As well as the costs involved in the implementati<strong>on</strong>, administrati<strong>on</strong>, m<strong>on</strong>itoring and<br />

enforcement of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, there may be other disadvantages. For example,<br />

community cynicism regarding industry regulating itself may lead to a distrust of<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> some issues and the industry as a whole may be blamed for the<br />

practices of <strong>on</strong>e or two disreputable firms. Individual firms that are not part of a<br />

self-regulatory scheme may also gain commercial advantages from having immunity<br />

from sancti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

As a general guide to whether self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is appropriate, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> endorses<br />

the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Office of Regulati<strong>on</strong> Review’s Regulatory Impact Statement<br />

checklist. The checklist states that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> should be c<strong>on</strong>sidered where:<br />

¾ there is no str<strong>on</strong>g public interest c<strong>on</strong>cern, in particular, no major public health<br />

and safety c<strong>on</strong>cern;<br />

¾ the problem is a low risk event, of low impact/significance, in other words the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> failing to resolve a specific problem are small;<br />

and<br />

9 Grey-letter Law: <strong>Report</strong> of the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Interdepartmental Committee <strong>on</strong> Quasi-regulati<strong>on</strong>, 1997.<br />

Available <strong>on</strong> the Internet at http://www.pc.gov.au/orr/.<br />

18


¾ the problem can be fixed by the market itself, in other words there is an<br />

incentive for individuals and groups to develop and comply with<br />

self-regulatory arrangements (e.g. for industry survival, or to gain a market<br />

advantage).<br />

However, changes in the industry envir<strong>on</strong>ment and market developments can effect<br />

the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s underpinning self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. It is important to m<strong>on</strong>itor<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to ensure that it is addressing what it was designed to achieve and to<br />

assess whether it is still the most appropriate form of interventi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

It is also evident that there is no <strong>on</strong>e model for self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

c<strong>on</strong>siders that good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> involves applying an appropriate<br />

scheme to a specific problem or objective. Ascertaining which scheme should be<br />

applied will depend <strong>on</strong> the nature and risk of the problem and the c<strong>on</strong>sequences of<br />

no acti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Chapter 5 will examine in more detail the industry envir<strong>on</strong>ments and market<br />

circumstances where self-regulati<strong>on</strong> may be appropriate and where it is not.<br />

19


Chapter 3<br />

Types of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets in Australia<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> is to inquire into and report <strong>on</strong> the types of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in use in<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets in Australia.<br />

Within the scope of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> there is a host of opti<strong>on</strong>s to deal with specific<br />

problems and objectives ranging from a simple code of ethics, to schemes<br />

incorporating codes that are drafted with legislative precisi<strong>on</strong> together with<br />

sophisticated customer dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms. The various forms of<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> at the nati<strong>on</strong>al level also cover a broad range of industries, including:<br />

¾ advertising;<br />

¾ broadcasting and the media;<br />

¾ direct marketing;<br />

¾ financial services sector;<br />

¾ general industry schemes;<br />

¾ pharmaceuticals and proprietary medicines;<br />

¾ professi<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>s;<br />

¾ retail sector schemes; and<br />

¾ telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

This chapter gives a snapshot of the reas<strong>on</strong>s for, and types of, self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. For<br />

further detail <strong>on</strong> the types of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, see the directory of self-regulatory<br />

schemes at the nati<strong>on</strong>al level in c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets. 10<br />

10 The directory of self-regulatory schemes can be found at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s website:<br />

www.treasury.gov.au/self-regtaskforce.<br />

20


C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

1. There is a broad and diverse range of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> at the nati<strong>on</strong>al level<br />

effecting c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

2. There is no single model for industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> as it depends <strong>on</strong> what is<br />

trying to be achieved.<br />

Reas<strong>on</strong>s for self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has found that the factors behind self-regulatory schemes range from<br />

marketing exercises to legislative requirements. The following secti<strong>on</strong> discusses these<br />

factors.<br />

Raising industry standards<br />

A comm<strong>on</strong> reas<strong>on</strong> for self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, often in c<strong>on</strong>juncti<strong>on</strong> with other reas<strong>on</strong>s, is the<br />

desire to raise industry standards. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is a means to exceed minimum<br />

legal requirements and can also enhance understanding and compliance with<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong>s. In a competitive envir<strong>on</strong>ment there is a str<strong>on</strong>g incentive for businesses to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tinually improve standards and exceed the benchmark service levels in order to<br />

gain market share. Various forms of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can set a benchmark for<br />

minimum service levels, and allow businesses flexibility in how these services are to<br />

be met and exceeded. For example, the Associati<strong>on</strong> of Superannuati<strong>on</strong> Funds of<br />

Australia has produced best practice papers <strong>on</strong> appointment of policy committees,<br />

member booklets and annual report checklists. 11<br />

Raising industry standards often refers to the ability to deal with rogue players or<br />

poor reputati<strong>on</strong>. The role of reputati<strong>on</strong> can be very important to a business,<br />

particularly when the business is operating in a competitive envir<strong>on</strong>ment. For<br />

example, the financial services industry is very competitive and values customer<br />

loyalty. One reas<strong>on</strong> as to why the Financial <strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Scheme was<br />

established was the emphasis the industry placed <strong>on</strong> measures for customer<br />

retenti<strong>on</strong> and customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. 12<br />

Marketing tool<br />

Using self-regulati<strong>on</strong> as a marketing tool is another reas<strong>on</strong> why self-regulati<strong>on</strong> has<br />

been developed by industry. Membership of a recognised form of self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

(e.g. code of c<strong>on</strong>duct) can often c<strong>on</strong>stitute an important selling point for businesses to<br />

11 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 22, p. 6.<br />

12 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 15, p. 2.<br />

21


attract new customers, and may increase the bargaining power of the business when<br />

entering new arrangements with other parties. Also, businesses can advertise the fact<br />

that they are in a self-regulatory scheme as a means of product differentiati<strong>on</strong>. For<br />

example, the <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong> Code enables c<strong>on</strong>sumers to<br />

differentiate between marketplace players. 13<br />

Similarly, in the grains industry, since most of Australia’s grain producti<strong>on</strong> is<br />

exported, <strong>on</strong>e of the means of achieving an edge for <strong>Australian</strong> grain in the<br />

competitive world market is to stress its high quality. Under the new privatised<br />

arrangements, the <strong>Australian</strong> Wheat Board Ltd sets the standards which growers<br />

must meet. 14<br />

Enhancing the level of informati<strong>on</strong><br />

Increasing the level of informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> products and services is a further reas<strong>on</strong> for<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. By enhancing informati<strong>on</strong> flows, businesses can boost c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

c<strong>on</strong>fidence in products. The Code of C<strong>on</strong>duct for the Provisi<strong>on</strong> of Informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Food<br />

Products was introduced to complement regulati<strong>on</strong>s and increase c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

knowledge. It provides a degree of c<strong>on</strong>sistency in food companies’ approaches to<br />

labelling and the use of terms to describe food products, thereby providing a greater<br />

degree of certainty and c<strong>on</strong>fidence to c<strong>on</strong>sumers about the nature of the products<br />

they are purchasing. 15<br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is also a means of building c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence when introducing<br />

new technology to the industry. For example, the <strong>Australian</strong> Code of Practice for<br />

Computerised Checkout Systems in Supermarkets was introduced to deal with the<br />

visibility of shelf labels, including the provisi<strong>on</strong> of free items when the scanned price<br />

is higher than the shelf price. 16<br />

Threat of government regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

The actual or perceived ‘threat’ of government regulati<strong>on</strong>, or a ‘push’ by government<br />

because of poor industry practices was found to be a further reas<strong>on</strong> for industry to<br />

self-regulate. For example, the Code of Banking Practice was primarily developed by a<br />

committee of officials and implemented by <strong>Australian</strong> banks. 17<br />

Legislative requirements<br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> may have also been imposed via legislative requirements. For<br />

example, in the telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s industry, Part 6 of the Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Act<br />

13 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 36, p. 11.<br />

14 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 28, p. 5.<br />

15 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 30, p. 15.<br />

16 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 11, p. 2.<br />

17 Grey-letter Law: <strong>Report</strong> of the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Interdepartmental Committee <strong>on</strong> Quasi-regulati<strong>on</strong>, 1997,<br />

p. XIII.<br />

22


1997 establishes a scheme of industry codes and industry standards. 18 Also, the Act<br />

provides for the Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman Scheme which is an<br />

independent alternative dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme. Membership of this scheme is a<br />

legislative requirement of all carriers and eligible carriage service providers.<br />

Similarly, under secti<strong>on</strong> 123 of the Broadcasting Services Act 1992, commercial<br />

broadcasting licensees are now required to develop codes of practice in c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong><br />

with the <strong>Australian</strong> Broadcasting Authority. 19<br />

Combinati<strong>on</strong> of factors<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that often there will be a number of reas<strong>on</strong>s to self-regulate.<br />

For instance, schemes may have been formed in part due to the threat of government<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong>. However, there were probably good reas<strong>on</strong>s why government was<br />

threatening to regulate in the first place such as the need to raise industry standards<br />

or to increase informati<strong>on</strong> flows. For example, the <strong>Australian</strong> Competiti<strong>on</strong> and<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Commissi<strong>on</strong> (ACCC) assisted the film industry to develop a code to avoid<br />

problems in the industry.<br />

18 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 17, p. 1.<br />

19 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 35, p. 5.<br />

23


<strong>Self</strong>-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>s available to industry<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> has an array of self-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>s available to address specific<br />

problems and objectives. These opti<strong>on</strong>s can range from a simple informati<strong>on</strong><br />

campaign to a complex dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme. In additi<strong>on</strong>, there is a spectrum<br />

within each type of self-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Informati<strong>on</strong> campaign<br />

At the lower end of the self-regulatory spectrum are informati<strong>on</strong> campaigns. As part<br />

of increasing the flow of informati<strong>on</strong>, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has found that educati<strong>on</strong> of both<br />

industry members and the c<strong>on</strong>sumer is important. For example, the <strong>Australian</strong> Cold<br />

Chain Guidelines seek to strengthen the cold chain by recommending practices for<br />

each link, from the manufacturer to c<strong>on</strong>sumer to ensure the safety and quality of<br />

frozen and chilled foods. 20<br />

Also, as discussed elsewhere, self-regulati<strong>on</strong> plays an important role in<br />

complementing regulati<strong>on</strong>. For example, the Resp<strong>on</strong>sible Serving of Alcohol<br />

Program complements the liquor licensing laws. Business and Professi<strong>on</strong>al Women<br />

of Australia commented that it is in businesses’ own interest to support the program<br />

as servers of alcohol can be charged for possible manslaughter when serving alcohol<br />

to drunken people. 21 Similarly, Coatings Care is a voluntary program which<br />

companies that deal with paints and coatings may follow to meet regulatory<br />

requirements in a manner complementary to their operati<strong>on</strong>s. The Department of<br />

<strong>Industry</strong>, Science and Resources submitted that the program assists companies to<br />

comply with the diverse requirements for protecting worker health, safety and the<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment. 22<br />

20 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 30, p. 16.<br />

21 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with Business and Professi<strong>on</strong>al Women of Australia, Melbourne,<br />

22 November 1999.<br />

22 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 31, pp. 11-12.<br />

24


Service charters<br />

Related to informati<strong>on</strong> campaigns, a service charter is a simple and short<br />

plain-language document which sets out the quality of service standards customers<br />

can expect to receive from that organisati<strong>on</strong>. As discussed in the ACCC’s submissi<strong>on</strong>,<br />

the move for service charters started in the United Kingdom in the early 1990s, but<br />

they are becoming increasingly popular in other countries. 23 In Australia, the<br />

Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Government and some State and local governments are<br />

implementing charters. Private companies are also starting to follow suit. For<br />

example, the AAMI insurance company has recently produced a service charter<br />

which sets out some clearly defined rights for its customers. 24<br />

Internal complaints handling departments and procedures<br />

Another form of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the use of internal complaints handling<br />

departments and procedures. Companies are increasingly looking at ways to gain a<br />

competitive edge over their rivals in the marketplace. In particular, bigger companies<br />

have an advantage in this area by virtue of their size. Many companies are now<br />

internalising c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> by establishing corporate c<strong>on</strong>sumer affairs<br />

departments. For example, the NRMA has a Customer Relati<strong>on</strong>s unit that provides<br />

services for customers such as interpreters and c<strong>on</strong>ference call facilities. 25<br />

A further development has been the use of internal complaints handling systems. For<br />

example, the Insurance Council of Australia pointed to the General Insurance Code of<br />

Practice establishing internal dispute arrangements within each insurer. 26 Generally,<br />

before a complaint goes to an external disputes scheme, businesses will try and solve<br />

it internally as a first port of call. Standards Australia, which is a n<strong>on</strong>-Government<br />

body, has also developed a Standard <strong>on</strong> Complaints Handling (AS4269). 27<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, companies have established their own internal/company-based<br />

compliance systems. Standards Australia has recently released an <strong>Australian</strong><br />

standard <strong>on</strong> Compliance Programs (AS3806). 28 This standard proposes requirements<br />

and recommendati<strong>on</strong>s for the development, implementati<strong>on</strong> and maintenance of a<br />

compliance system that can assist an organisati<strong>on</strong> in its compliance with the law.<br />

23 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 42, p. 31.<br />

24 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the Society of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Professi<strong>on</strong>als in Business,<br />

Canberra, 7 December 1999.<br />

25 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 7, p. 4.<br />

26 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 18, p. 2.<br />

27 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 42, p. 32.<br />

28 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 42, p. 31.<br />

25


Accreditati<strong>on</strong>, licensing and membership certificati<strong>on</strong><br />

Accreditati<strong>on</strong>, licensing and membership certificati<strong>on</strong>s are a means to create<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence in the level of professi<strong>on</strong>alism and technical competence of<br />

members of industry and professi<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>s. It also serves to set standards<br />

within an industry or professi<strong>on</strong>. For example, the accounting professi<strong>on</strong> requires<br />

prospective members to complete professi<strong>on</strong>al accreditati<strong>on</strong> programs prior to being<br />

admitted as either a certified practising accountant or chartered accountant. 29<br />

Quality assurance systems<br />

Quality assurance systems (QAS) are another form self-regulati<strong>on</strong> that aim to<br />

enhance the quality of a good or service. For example, the increasing adopti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

QAS reflects the widespread recogniti<strong>on</strong> of the emerging role quality management is<br />

playing in world agrifood markets. In the meat and livestock industry, Flockcare is<br />

an <strong>on</strong>-farm QAS introduced by the Sheepmeat Council of Australia to provide a<br />

systematic way to ensure producers supply a safe, c<strong>on</strong>sistent product while reducing<br />

waste and <strong>on</strong>-farm costs. 30<br />

Standards<br />

Another comm<strong>on</strong> type of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the use of standards. Many standards are<br />

developed to provide a dem<strong>on</strong>strati<strong>on</strong> that certain technical requirements are being<br />

met. For example, there are standards in engineering that need to be met before a<br />

professi<strong>on</strong>al engineer is registered. These standards of competency are measured<br />

against a benchmark at the time of first registrati<strong>on</strong> and are required to be<br />

progressively enhanced through c<strong>on</strong>tinuing professi<strong>on</strong>al development. 31<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> standards are c<strong>on</strong>sensus-based voluntary documents with which<br />

compliance is n<strong>on</strong>-mandatory unless incorporated into law or called up in<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tractual documents. For example, Standards Australia has published four toy<br />

safety standards (AS1647 series) which apply to the c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> of toys so that the<br />

risk of ingesti<strong>on</strong> for children less than three years of age is reduced. 32 Presently, <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

<strong>on</strong>e of these standards for small parts has been declared mandatory.<br />

Codes and dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes<br />

By far the most comm<strong>on</strong> form of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct or codes of ethics<br />

that are usually built around membership of a professi<strong>on</strong>al or industry associati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Codes can range from setting out general statements of principle about how an<br />

industry or business will operate, to listing specific business practices which are<br />

29 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 33, p. 2.<br />

30 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 28, p. 2.<br />

31 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 26, p. 17.<br />

32 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 23, p. 2.<br />

26


guaranteed. They can either c<strong>on</strong>tain minimum standards or standards, which are,<br />

aimed at best practice.<br />

Instituti<strong>on</strong>al and functi<strong>on</strong>al codes<br />

Codes can also be instituti<strong>on</strong>al or functi<strong>on</strong>al in their nature. Most codes are<br />

instituti<strong>on</strong>ally based — that is, codes are industry based. As discussed in chapter 5 —<br />

industry envir<strong>on</strong>ment and market circumstances where self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be<br />

most effective, a major c<strong>on</strong>tributing factor to an effective code of c<strong>on</strong>duct is the<br />

strength of industry support. However, some products/services can exist across<br />

different sectors and industries. Hence a functi<strong>on</strong>al self-regulatory scheme covers<br />

products/services that span more than <strong>on</strong>e industry. An example of a functi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

code is the <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong> (ADMA) Code. ADMA<br />

represents over 400 organisati<strong>on</strong>s involved in informati<strong>on</strong>-based marketing<br />

including financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s, publishers, catalogue and mail order traders,<br />

Internet-based marketers and service providers, airlines and travel services,<br />

telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s service providers, and a host of other users and suppliers of<br />

direct marketing services. 33<br />

Dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

Codes can also differ in other respects, including whether or not they provide a<br />

method of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> depending <strong>on</strong> the nature of the specific problems trying<br />

to be addressed. For example, the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Code for the Safe Producti<strong>on</strong> of Enzymatic<br />

Detergents allows the manufacture of enzymatic detergents in Australia. Following<br />

the producti<strong>on</strong> requirements of the code, manufacturers m<strong>on</strong>itor their workplaces<br />

using the analytical procedures it specifies to ensure that employees are not exposed<br />

to enzyme dust. 34 Whereas, there are a number codes that have an accompanying<br />

alternate dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> (ADR) scheme. Some of the biggest ADR schemes are the<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> Banking <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman, the Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong><br />

Ombudsman, and the General Insurance Enquiries and Complaints Scheme.<br />

Sancti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Codes may also differ in their level of sancti<strong>on</strong>s for n<strong>on</strong>-compliance. The Jewellery and<br />

Timepieces <strong>Industry</strong> Code lists the types of remedial acti<strong>on</strong> that can apply when the<br />

code is breached such as withdrawal of, or corrective advertising, writing to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers, offering c<strong>on</strong>sumers a refund, offering alternative merchandise or offering<br />

a raincheck. 35<br />

Compliance<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, compliance by industry with a code of c<strong>on</strong>duct can be mandatory or<br />

voluntary. For example, secti<strong>on</strong> 113 of the Insurance Act 1973 makes it mandatory for<br />

general insurers of certain types of policies to be members of the General Insurance<br />

33 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 36, p. 2.<br />

34 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 27, p. 9.<br />

35 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the Jewellers Associati<strong>on</strong> of Australia, Canberra, 7 December 1999.<br />

27


Code of Practice. 36 In c<strong>on</strong>trast, the advertising self-regulatory scheme is voluntary in its<br />

nature and participants do not have to abide by the Advertising Board’s<br />

determinati<strong>on</strong>s. 37<br />

In effect, there is a spectrum of different codes within the codes framework. This<br />

re-iterates the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s finding that there is no <strong>on</strong>e model for self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

36 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 18, p. 6.<br />

37 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 12, p. 2.<br />

28


Chapter 4<br />

Gaps and overlaps in the<br />

coverage of self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> is to inquire into and report <strong>on</strong> gaps and overlaps in the coverage of<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

There has been c<strong>on</strong>siderable growth in the number of self-regulatory schemes across<br />

many industries. In additi<strong>on</strong>, these self-regulatory schemes operate in dynamic<br />

markets, which are influenced by globalisati<strong>on</strong>, increasing vertical integrati<strong>on</strong>, and<br />

the growth of ‘hybrid’ products that span traditi<strong>on</strong>al markets or industries.<br />

As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence, gaps and overlaps can emerge in the coverage of various<br />

products, services, sectors and industries. For example, a specific problem may<br />

emerge from the use of new technology in an industry and may not be covered by<br />

any form of regulati<strong>on</strong>. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is <strong>on</strong>e means to overcome any specific<br />

problems associated with the new technology. Similarly, some self-regulatory<br />

schemes may have a degree of overlap where the distincti<strong>on</strong> between products or<br />

services has become blurred.<br />

This chapter looks at the broad gaps and overlaps in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in Australia.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

3. Gaps and overlaps c<strong>on</strong>tinually emerge and re-emerge in dynamic markets;<br />

4. A ‘gap’ in the market does not necessarily mean that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the<br />

appropriate soluti<strong>on</strong>;<br />

5. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is a flexible resp<strong>on</strong>se to market failure and may fill a ‘gap’<br />

quickly and efficiently; and<br />

6. Some small businesses can have difficulties in joining self-regulatory schemes<br />

as can c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

29


C<strong>on</strong>verging sectors and product lines<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that with increased technology and increasing merger of<br />

product lines and new products, there will always be gaps and overlaps emerging.<br />

Therefore, it is important to m<strong>on</strong>itor self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to ensure that it is addressing<br />

what it was designed to achieve and to assess whether it is still the most appropriate<br />

form of interventi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The financial services industry is an example of an industry that is undergoing rapid<br />

and c<strong>on</strong>tinuous change with new technology and new products. There is also an<br />

increasing merger of product lines. For example, some banks are now selling<br />

insurance policies under separate entities.<br />

Similarly, in the telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s sector gaps and overlaps may increase as<br />

technology and discrete industries c<strong>on</strong>verge. Presently, separate self-regulatory<br />

arrangements currently apply to the telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s, Internet and broadcasting<br />

industries. The Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman stated that at the moment<br />

there are <strong>on</strong>ly a few and episodic instances of self-regulatory overlap, although the<br />

nature of these overlaps, driven by c<strong>on</strong>vergence of both technology and of<br />

previously discrete industries, suggest that they will increase. 38 Similarly, the Service<br />

Providers <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that there are daily examples where such<br />

separati<strong>on</strong> is proving problematic, for example in digital televisi<strong>on</strong>, datacasting, and<br />

Internet c<strong>on</strong>tent. 39 Cable & Wireless Optus also commented that as the technologies<br />

of these industries c<strong>on</strong>verge, there will be an increasing need for regulatory schemes<br />

to resp<strong>on</strong>d in a manner which enables industries to deliver market efficiencies. 40<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> discusses the role of instituti<strong>on</strong>al and functi<strong>on</strong>al self-regulatory<br />

schemes whilst weighing up the importance of industry ownership in chapter 8 ⎯<br />

Opti<strong>on</strong>s that facilitate the improvement and harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

schemes.<br />

Globalisati<strong>on</strong><br />

The markets in which businesses operate are also becoming increasingly global, with<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers trading <strong>on</strong>line with merchants all over the world. In particular, Internet<br />

use has increased global competiti<strong>on</strong> in c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets. As a result,<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> initiatives need to take into account internati<strong>on</strong>al as well as domestic<br />

industry participants.<br />

38 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 21, p. 7.<br />

39 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 25, p. 2.<br />

40 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 6, p. 5.<br />

30


The <strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong> stated that c<strong>on</strong>sumers are increasingly<br />

interacting across jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s and finding examples of good practice. If domestic<br />

industry is going to compete in this market it will need to match these practices. 41<br />

Similarly, the NRMA c<strong>on</strong>sidered that with the increasingly globalised nature of<br />

many markets and the growth of e-commerce, there is a need for internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of codes. 42 Clayt<strong>on</strong> Utz stated that dialogue between industry bodies<br />

in Australia and in overseas markets should be actively encouraged and pursued to<br />

develop harm<strong>on</strong>ious self-regulatory schemes which encourage bilateral trade and<br />

discourage protecti<strong>on</strong>ism where possible. Clayt<strong>on</strong> Utz submitted that subscripti<strong>on</strong> to<br />

overseas self-regulati<strong>on</strong> schemes by <strong>Australian</strong> organisati<strong>on</strong>s and subscripti<strong>on</strong> to<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> schemes by foreign organisati<strong>on</strong>s should also be encouraged. The<br />

development of internati<strong>on</strong>al or multi-jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>al self-regulati<strong>on</strong> schemes could<br />

also occur. 43<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Toy Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that any imposts or obligati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong><br />

companies under self-regulatory arrangements should not disadvantage <strong>Australian</strong><br />

companies via internati<strong>on</strong>al competiti<strong>on</strong>. 44 Similarly, the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Furnishing<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> of Australia commented that its code is becoming a burden in<br />

terms of competing against cheap imports. 45 Harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> will help prevent<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> businesses from losing customers to overseas countries that may offer<br />

cheaper products but provide less c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> through industry<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

In developing and modifying self-regulatory schemes, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that<br />

the impact of globalisati<strong>on</strong> needs to be c<strong>on</strong>sidered. The challenge is to implement<br />

schemes that provide choice and security for the c<strong>on</strong>sumer while enhancing<br />

competitiveness of <strong>Australian</strong> business.<br />

Gaps in the market<br />

Is self-regulati<strong>on</strong> appropriate?<br />

As discussed in chapter 2, the type of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> (or any regulati<strong>on</strong>) should<br />

depend <strong>on</strong> what is trying to be achieved. The following chapter (chapter 5) discusses<br />

the general market circumstances and industry envir<strong>on</strong>ments where self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

may be appropriate.<br />

41 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 16, p. 2.<br />

42 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 7, p. 6.<br />

43 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 43, p. 4.<br />

44 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 23, p. 3.<br />

45 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Furnishing <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> of Australia,<br />

Melbourne, 23 November 1999.<br />

31


Hence, a ‘gap’ in a market where there is no form of regulati<strong>on</strong> may not necessarily<br />

mean that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the answer. In fact, no regulati<strong>on</strong>, or explicit government<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> could be the minimum effective soluti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> stresses that the specific problems and/or objectives need to be clearly<br />

specified before any type of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is c<strong>on</strong>sidered, then the benefits and costs<br />

of ways to deal with the problem can be analysed together with c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with<br />

effected parties.<br />

If self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the appropriate tool to deal with specific problems and/or<br />

objectives, then the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that self-regulatory schemes can be very<br />

flexible and resp<strong>on</strong>sive and to market circumstances and a changing industry<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment. For example, the Teleph<strong>on</strong>e Informati<strong>on</strong> Services Standards Council<br />

was set up by industry in resp<strong>on</strong>se to c<strong>on</strong>sumer complaints about primarily<br />

‘0055/1900’ teleph<strong>on</strong>e numbers. The Council has also been modified to include new<br />

competitors such as Optus and service providers. 46<br />

Small business<br />

Some small businesses can find it difficult, or may be unwilling, to be part of a<br />

self-regulatory scheme, perhaps because they do not perceive themselves as<br />

bel<strong>on</strong>ging to a particular industry segment. The Micro Business Network stated that<br />

those businesses that are not currently involved in an industry associati<strong>on</strong> would<br />

find it hard to regulate and many small businesses are anti-regulati<strong>on</strong> from a general<br />

viewpoint. 47 Similarly, the Office of Small Business suggested that it is generally<br />

accepted that small business is less able than big business to cope with the costs of<br />

participating in a scheme such as a code of c<strong>on</strong>duct, particularly when such a scheme<br />

is funded by industry levies. The Office of Small Business asserted that small<br />

businesses in many cases have no opti<strong>on</strong> but to pass <strong>on</strong> these costs to the c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

in the form of higher prices for goods and services. It argued that this can place small<br />

business at a competitive disadvantage to their larger counterparts. 48<br />

The Office of Small Business commented that although small businesses often have<br />

legal recourse in disputes, their access to justice can be c<strong>on</strong>strained by the cost of<br />

going to court, delays before their case is heard, the disparity in the quality of<br />

representati<strong>on</strong> and their need to preserve business relati<strong>on</strong>ships. It suggested that in<br />

many cases, neither party achieves a satisfactory result from a Court judgement. 49<br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulatory approaches can offer small business a low-cost, quick and flexible<br />

system for resolving disputes. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> can also assist small business to<br />

understand and comply with the law.<br />

46 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the Teleph<strong>on</strong>e Informati<strong>on</strong> Services Standards Council, Sydney,<br />

1 March 1999.<br />

47 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 2, p. 1.<br />

48 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 38, p. 3.<br />

49 Ibid.<br />

32


The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> discusses ways in which self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can be more readily accessible<br />

to small businesses in chapter 6 — good practice and cost-effective practice in<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. This discussi<strong>on</strong> includes items such as the funding of schemes not<br />

placing businesses at a competitive disadvantage, a transparency of fees, and<br />

possible small business representati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Awareness of codes<br />

Another issue that could be loosely termed as a ‘gap’ is that c<strong>on</strong>sumers may not be<br />

aware of various dispute-handling schemes. The C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre of Victoria,<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit Legal Service of Victoria and the Financial and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Rights<br />

Council of Victoria suggested that <strong>on</strong>ly a small proporti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Australian</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumers<br />

are empowered to be able to advocate <strong>on</strong> their own behalf within the marketplace<br />

and challenge unsatisfactory behaviour by industries. 50 Further, the Law Council of<br />

Australia points out that statistics often do not take into account the reas<strong>on</strong>s why and<br />

how the disputes are resolved but simply state that they are ‘resolved’. The Council<br />

argues that many of the disputes are resolved through c<strong>on</strong>sumer frustrati<strong>on</strong> and<br />

ultimate aband<strong>on</strong>ment of complaints. 51<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Redress Study (1999) identified the most and least comm<strong>on</strong><br />

demographic characteristics of a typical user of a redress mechanism: 52<br />

50 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 29, p. 12.<br />

51 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 19, p. 5.<br />

52 C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Divisi<strong>on</strong>, Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Department of Treasury 1999, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Redress<br />

Study, released by the Minister for Financial Services and Regulati<strong>on</strong>, the H<strong>on</strong> Joe Hockey MP.<br />

This document is available <strong>on</strong> the Internet at http://www.treasury.gov.au (choose C<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

Affairs/Publicati<strong>on</strong>s/<strong>Industry</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-Regulati<strong>on</strong> Publicati<strong>on</strong>s).<br />

33


Most Comm<strong>on</strong><br />

Age Sex Educati<strong>on</strong> Level Employment<br />

45-54 Male At least completed<br />

high school<br />

35-44 Male Some tertiary<br />

Least Comm<strong>on</strong><br />

educati<strong>on</strong><br />

Status<br />

Age Sex Educati<strong>on</strong> Level Employment<br />

18-24 Female Did not complete<br />

high school<br />

34<br />

First<br />

Language<br />

Place of Residence<br />

Full-time English Metropolitan<br />

Full-time English Metropolitan<br />

Status<br />

First<br />

Language<br />

Place of Residence<br />

Part-time N<strong>on</strong>-English Remote Area<br />

While the sample data were relatively small, and therefore generalisati<strong>on</strong>s from the<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> should be made with cauti<strong>on</strong>, the survey outcomes reflect the experience<br />

of the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre of Victoria, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit Legal Service of Victoria<br />

and the Financial and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Rights Council of Victoria. Further, the results are<br />

echoed in data collected by the Energy <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman of Victoria in relati<strong>on</strong><br />

to the demographics of its complainants. 53<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that this stresses the importance of effective c<strong>on</strong>sumer access<br />

to self-regulati<strong>on</strong> (see further discussi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> this in chapter 6 — good practice and<br />

cost-effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> methods and approaches).<br />

Regulatory gaps in the market<br />

A number of organisati<strong>on</strong>s brought to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s attenti<strong>on</strong> the existence of gaps<br />

in particular markets or industries.<br />

The joint submissi<strong>on</strong> from the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre of Victoria, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit<br />

Legal Service of Victoria and the Financial and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Rights Council of Victoria<br />

submitted that there are a number of gaps in markets. For example, they submitted<br />

that there are gaps in the airline industry, financial services industry, food industry<br />

and in telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s. They commented that there is a need for urgent and<br />

appropriate resp<strong>on</strong>ses to maintain public faith in co-regulatory processes. 54<br />

53 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 29, p. 12.<br />

54 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 29, pp. 3-9.


The <strong>Australian</strong> Securities and Investments Commissi<strong>on</strong> (ASIC) also commented that<br />

there are gaps in the coverage of formal alternative dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes in the<br />

finance services industry including:<br />

¾ credit (finance companies, building societies and some credit uni<strong>on</strong>s); 55<br />

¾ accountants (although accountants that provide financial advice are required to<br />

be members of an alternative dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme);<br />

¾ real estate investments other than real estate managed investments;<br />

¾ some ‘transacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly’ activities (e.g. <strong>on</strong>-line share broking services); and<br />

¾ some cross-border financial services.<br />

However, ASIC commented that it does not believe that all these areas need<br />

immediate coverage, but rather that c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> should be given as to whether the<br />

absence of coverage by dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes is a reflecti<strong>on</strong> of a lack of market<br />

problems or because of the difficulties in establishing schemes in such areas. 56<br />

NSW Legal Aid also commented that there are gaps in c<strong>on</strong>sumer credit insurance<br />

policies. 57<br />

Further, the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre of Victoria observed that interest rates have been<br />

very high in the pawnbroking industry, and there has been no push by the industry<br />

to set up a code of practice. The Centre commented that any self-regulatory scheme<br />

should look at the types of c<strong>on</strong>sumers using the service. 58<br />

The C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Committee of the Law Council of Australia also observed that<br />

there is a gap in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> regarding Queensland property developers.<br />

Marketers are charging higher prices for interstate buyers than locals. However, the<br />

Committee commented that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> may not work here as the industry does<br />

not have any interest in setting up a scheme. 59<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> re-iterates that a gap in the market where there is no form of<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> may not necessarily mean that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the most appropriate<br />

soluti<strong>on</strong>, or indeed that any form of regulati<strong>on</strong> is required. The type of interventi<strong>on</strong><br />

(if any) will depend <strong>on</strong> the nature of the specific problem and should be the effective<br />

minimum soluti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

55 The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> notes that under the Uniform C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit Code, c<strong>on</strong>sumer credit is the<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>sibility of the States.<br />

56 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 22.<br />

57 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 24, p. 6.<br />

58 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the Victorian C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre, Melbourne, 23 November<br />

1999.<br />

59 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Committee of the Law Council of Australia,<br />

Canberra, 6 December 1999. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> also notes that this issue is outside the<br />

Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth’s resp<strong>on</strong>sibility.<br />

35


Overlap in the market<br />

Overlapping schemes<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> believes that in the great majority of cases the nature of any c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

complaint is likely to make the appropriate code self-evident. For example, if there<br />

are c<strong>on</strong>cerns over an advertisement, then the c<strong>on</strong>sumer can complain to the<br />

Advertising Board. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> is c<strong>on</strong>scious of the need for a seamless transiti<strong>on</strong><br />

between and am<strong>on</strong>g codes for the benefit of c<strong>on</strong>sumers and to avoid duplicati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

costs. It is vital to retain the ‘<strong>on</strong>e stop shop’ approach to complaints handling. From<br />

the c<strong>on</strong>sumers’ perspective, a multiple complaints handling envir<strong>on</strong>ment can be<br />

inefficient, burdensome and frequently frustrating.<br />

However, as discussed above, the growth of different products and changing<br />

technology means that there can be multiple schemes in an industry (e.g. financial<br />

services industry). For example, ASIC commented that the Financial <strong>Industry</strong><br />

Complaints Scheme (FICS) and Financial Services Complaint Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Scheme had<br />

a substantial degree of overlap in the area of complaints about licensees who provide<br />

investment advice to retail investors and about resp<strong>on</strong>sible entities of managed<br />

investment schemes. These schemes were merged <strong>on</strong> 1 January 2000, and will now<br />

operate under the FICS banner. ASIC commented that this merger will deliver both<br />

cost savings to industry and more c<strong>on</strong>sistent complaints handling for c<strong>on</strong>sumers. 60<br />

In c<strong>on</strong>trast, the <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong> suggested that overlapping<br />

codes is a strength rather than a weakness of self-regulatory systems. 61 Indeed it is<br />

arguable that some degree of overlap is necessary in order for these systems to be<br />

effective since any significant number of complaints ‘falling between the cracks’<br />

would tend to bring the whole system into questi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

As a general rule, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that any significant overlap between<br />

schemes should be avoided. Further, multiple schemes in the same sector can be<br />

c<strong>on</strong>fusing for c<strong>on</strong>sumers. As pointed out by the NSW Legal Aid it has the potential<br />

for members to seek out the scheme that they perceive will be most sympathetic to<br />

them. 62<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> also encourages industry groups that administer complaints handling<br />

systems to have their own networks to ensure complaints are channelled<br />

appropriately. These networks need to be c<strong>on</strong>stantly nurtured. For example, in the<br />

financial services industry, the General Insurance and Enquiries and Complaints<br />

scheme stated that c<strong>on</strong>sumers are referred between schemes where necessary. This<br />

scheme and the Financial <strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Scheme (FICS), have a direct<br />

teleph<strong>on</strong>e line between the services so that c<strong>on</strong>sumers may be transferred directly<br />

60 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 21.<br />

61 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 36, p. 10.<br />

62 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 24, p. 7.<br />

36


when necessary. In additi<strong>on</strong>, these schemes also regularly participate in roundtable<br />

meetings with other dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme managers and with ASIC. 63<br />

Multiple membership of codes<br />

A related issue to scheme overlap is that companies may be members of more than<br />

<strong>on</strong>e code and disputes scheme, and for larger companies this can extend to three or<br />

four. For example a major finance company providing banking and insurance<br />

services directly to c<strong>on</strong>sumers may bel<strong>on</strong>g to the Banking Code, the General<br />

Insurance Code of Practice and the Code of the <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing<br />

Associati<strong>on</strong>. 64 Similarly, in the telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s industry, some industry players<br />

participate in multiple forums, such as the <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

Code, or the Internet <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> Code. 65<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong> to multiple schemes, there is also often a mix of self-regulatory and<br />

regulatory frameworks companies have to comply with, as well as nati<strong>on</strong>al and State<br />

schemes.<br />

In the financial services industry, to the extent that schemes c<strong>on</strong>tinue to operate<br />

al<strong>on</strong>g sectoral or industry lines (e.g. general insurance, life insurance and managed<br />

investments, banking) the ASIC requirement to join an approved scheme means that<br />

there will be circumstances in which participants are members of more than <strong>on</strong>e<br />

scheme. For example, a bank that is a member of the <strong>Australian</strong> Banking <strong>Industry</strong><br />

Ombudsman will be required to join an approved scheme (currently Financial<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Scheme) in respect of its retail advisory activities.<br />

It can be c<strong>on</strong>fusing and costly for companies to comply with multiple schemes.<br />

However, it is important to recognise industry differences and tailor self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

to the circumstances of each industry. Also, there are other factors driving multiple<br />

schemes such as the dynamic nature of markets and companies delving into different<br />

products and services.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that better co-ordinati<strong>on</strong> of self-regulatory schemes may<br />

allay these c<strong>on</strong>cerns. Some approaches to coordinate self-regulati<strong>on</strong> are discussed in<br />

chapter 7 — approaches to promoting and coordinating industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

including the appropriate role of government.<br />

63 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 8, p. 3.<br />

64 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 18, p. 5.<br />

65 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with Government agencies, Canberra, 6 December 1999.<br />

37


Chapter 5<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> envir<strong>on</strong>ment and market circumstances<br />

where self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be most effective<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> is to inquire into and report <strong>on</strong> those industry envir<strong>on</strong>ments and<br />

market circumstances where different types of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> are likely to be most<br />

effective.<br />

There is a general recogniti<strong>on</strong> that industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is often more flexible and<br />

less costly for both business and c<strong>on</strong>sumers than direct government involvement. 66<br />

However, it is necessary to ensure that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the appropriate form of<br />

interventi<strong>on</strong> given particular industry envir<strong>on</strong>ment and market circumstances,<br />

otherwise inappropriate interventi<strong>on</strong> could create new problems.<br />

There has already been some work d<strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong> the market prec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for effective<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. However, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> was keen to not <strong>on</strong>ly learn from other work<br />

that has analysed where self-regulati<strong>on</strong> may be most effective, but also wanted<br />

rigorous analysis c<strong>on</strong>ducted to test hypotheses. The importance placed <strong>on</strong> a<br />

comprehensive and thorough analysis of market circumstances where industry<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> was likely to be most and least effective, became the catalyst for the<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> to engage a c<strong>on</strong>sultant. 67 The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> required the c<strong>on</strong>sultant to structure<br />

research around case studies where industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> had been implemented.<br />

The aim of this research was not to identify self-regulatory success and failure in<br />

particular industries but to more broadly identify the characteristics of the<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment and market that have influenced the effectiveness of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

This chapter draws out the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> findings based <strong>on</strong> a review of existing<br />

informati<strong>on</strong>, the views of stakeholders collected through the c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> process,<br />

and advice from the c<strong>on</strong>sultant.<br />

66 See chapter 6.<br />

67 Tasman Asia Pacific 2000, Analysis of market circumstances where industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to<br />

be most and least effective. Its report can be located at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> webpage at<br />

http://www.treasury.gov.au/self-regtaskforce.<br />

39


C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Nature and extent of market failure<br />

7. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be most effective where there are clearly defined<br />

problems but no high risk of serious or widespread harm to c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

Market structure<br />

8. An industry envir<strong>on</strong>ment with an active industry associati<strong>on</strong> and/or industry<br />

cohesiveness is most likely to administer effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> as industry<br />

participants are more likely to commit financial resources, c<strong>on</strong>sult with<br />

stakeholders and m<strong>on</strong>itor the effectiveness of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

9. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is less effective where there is a broad spread of smaller<br />

businesses that do not communicate with each other.<br />

10. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is most likely to be effective in a competitive market as<br />

industry participants are more likely to be ‘compliant c<strong>on</strong>scious’ to<br />

differentiate their products, or in fear of losing market share.<br />

11. A more mature industry may be able to administer more effective<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, as industry participants are more likely to have sufficient<br />

resources and be more committed while any ‘shakeout’ of rogue traders will<br />

already have occurred.<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>sumer interests<br />

12. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be most effective where firms recognise that their<br />

future viability depends not <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong> their relati<strong>on</strong>ship with their current<br />

customers and shareholders, but also <strong>on</strong> the wider community.<br />

13. The more incentives there are for industry participants to initiate and comply<br />

with self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, then the more chance a scheme can remedy specific<br />

industry problems.<br />

14. The extent to which industry participants are prepared to sign up to a<br />

self-regulatory scheme will affect the ability of that scheme to provide<br />

effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. Where a scheme has a high level of c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

recogniti<strong>on</strong>, to the point where c<strong>on</strong>sumers will favour scheme participants<br />

when making purchasing decisi<strong>on</strong>s, then the scheme is most likely to be<br />

effective. This will create incentives for n<strong>on</strong>-members to join the scheme.<br />

15. Where there are cost advantages and/or increased flexibility in<br />

self-regulatory initiatives to address specific industry problems compared<br />

with government regulati<strong>on</strong> or the court system, then there is a greater<br />

chance of improving market outcomes for both business and c<strong>on</strong>sumers, and<br />

minimising compliance costs for businesses.<br />

40


Office of Regulati<strong>on</strong> Review checklist<br />

There has already been some work d<strong>on</strong>e in identifying industry envir<strong>on</strong>ments and<br />

market circumstances that are more likely to lead to effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. In<br />

particular, a general guide to whether self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is appropriate is the<br />

Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Office of Regulati<strong>on</strong> Review’s Regulatory Impact Statement<br />

checklist. The checklist states that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> should be c<strong>on</strong>sidered where:<br />

¾ there is no str<strong>on</strong>g public interest c<strong>on</strong>cern, in particular, no major public health<br />

and safety c<strong>on</strong>cern;<br />

¾ the problem is a low risk event, of low impact/significance, in other words the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> failing to resolve a specific problem are small;<br />

and<br />

¾ the problem can be fixed by the market itself, in other words there is an<br />

incentive for individuals and groups to develop and comply with<br />

self-regulatory arrangements (e.g. for industry survival, or to gain a market<br />

advantage).<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, for self-regulatory industry schemes, the checklist determines success<br />

factors to include:<br />

¾ presence of a viable industry associati<strong>on</strong>;<br />

¾ adequate coverage of the industry by the industry associati<strong>on</strong>;<br />

¾ cohesive industry with like minded/motivated participants committed to<br />

achieving the goals;<br />

¾ voluntary participati<strong>on</strong> — effective sancti<strong>on</strong>s and incentives can be applied,<br />

with low scope for the benefits being shared with n<strong>on</strong>-participants; and<br />

¾ cost advantages from tailor-made soluti<strong>on</strong>s and less formal mechanisms such as<br />

access to quick complaints handling and redress mechanisms. 68<br />

During the inquiry, these observati<strong>on</strong>s were often reinforced and expanded up<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The following secti<strong>on</strong>s discuss these observati<strong>on</strong>s and other industry envir<strong>on</strong>ments<br />

and market circumstances where self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is more likely to be effective.<br />

68 Office of Regulati<strong>on</strong> Review 1998, A Guide to Regulati<strong>on</strong>, 2nd editi<strong>on</strong>. This publicati<strong>on</strong> is<br />

available from the following website: www.pc.gov.au/orr/.<br />

41


Nature and extent of market failure<br />

Clearly defined problems and low risk of serious or widespread harm to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is most effective where there are clearly<br />

defined problems and low risk of serious or widespread harm to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. In other<br />

words, the c<strong>on</strong>sequences of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> failing to resolve a specific problem<br />

would not seriously harm c<strong>on</strong>sumers. Where there are str<strong>on</strong>g public interest<br />

c<strong>on</strong>cerns, such as major health and safety issues, and the specific problems are of<br />

high risk and/or high frequency then other forms of regulati<strong>on</strong> may be more<br />

appropriate.<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Food and Grocery Council commented that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is most<br />

suitable where there is no str<strong>on</strong>g public interest, health or safety c<strong>on</strong>cern and the<br />

potential market failure would result in an event of low risk. 69<br />

Cable & Wireless Optus suggested that it is important to realise that the<br />

self-regulatory process cannot be used to resolve all competitive and public policy<br />

issues that arise within the industry. It submitted where there are significant<br />

competiti<strong>on</strong> issues or where the commercial interests of carriers with significant<br />

power are affected, self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is relatively ineffective in driving policy change<br />

expeditiously. Therefore, Cable & Wireless Optus argued that there clearly remains a<br />

significant role for statutory bodies in regulating industries particularly those<br />

dominated by vertically integrated m<strong>on</strong>opolies with significant market power. 70<br />

PowerTel also commented that there are elements of regulati<strong>on</strong> that must be kept<br />

outside of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> such as m<strong>on</strong>opoly c<strong>on</strong>trol. 71<br />

In the agriculture, fisheries and forestry industries, the Department of Agriculture,<br />

Forestry and Fisheries Australia recognised that there will be circumstances in which<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> may not be the most appropriate form of regulati<strong>on</strong>. It commented<br />

that the expectati<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>Australian</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumers and customers overseas will see some<br />

form of statutory regulati<strong>on</strong> in relati<strong>on</strong> to food safety and in the area of import and<br />

export inspecti<strong>on</strong> and the management of agricultural and veterinary chemicals for<br />

some time to come. 72<br />

The Instituti<strong>on</strong> of Engineers commented that explicit regulati<strong>on</strong> rather than<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> should regulate the engineering services that result in risk to the<br />

health, safety and welfare of the community. For the public, the risk of inadequate<br />

engineering depends <strong>on</strong> their exposure to engineering services. It submitted that<br />

69 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 30, p. 3.<br />

70 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 6, pp. 2-3.<br />

71 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 9, p. 1.<br />

72 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 28, p. 18.<br />

42


every pers<strong>on</strong>’s lifestyle is dependent <strong>on</strong> engineering via transport, communicati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

manufacturing and utilities. 73<br />

Standards Australia commented that a risk based approach should be taken into<br />

account when deciding whether regulati<strong>on</strong>s should be put into place with the level of<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> being assessed against the potential harm resulting from<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-compliance. 74<br />

Similarly, the c<strong>on</strong>sultant’s report submitted that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> will be more effective<br />

where the product supplied is not essential to the welfare of individuals. The<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sultant’s report submitted that the effectiveness of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> as a means of<br />

achieving such social welfare objectives depends <strong>on</strong> the extent to which firms have<br />

both the incentive and ability to achieve them. In general, the incentive for firms to<br />

self-regulate will be greater, the greater the extent to which those firms stand to<br />

benefit from those self-regulatory activities. 75<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> was interested to learn that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> tends to be more effective<br />

in those markets where c<strong>on</strong>sumers and other individuals in the community who are<br />

adversely affected by market failure share a comm<strong>on</strong> interest in eliminating that<br />

market failure. 76<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> involves applying an<br />

appropriate scheme to a specific problem or objective. Ascertaining which scheme<br />

should be applied will depend <strong>on</strong> the nature and risk of the problem and the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences of no acti<strong>on</strong>. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is most<br />

effective where there are clearly defined problems and a low risk of serious or<br />

widespread harm to c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

Market structure<br />

Active industry associati<strong>on</strong><br />

A major c<strong>on</strong>tributing factor to effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the strength of industry<br />

support. Evidence of industry support can be gauged by the existence of an industry<br />

associati<strong>on</strong>. The ability and willingness of industry to organise itself collectively<br />

dem<strong>on</strong>strates a capacity to undertake self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. An active industry associati<strong>on</strong><br />

is most likely to lead to industry participants meeting the schemes’ objectives.<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Food and Grocery Council argued that active, well resourced<br />

industry associati<strong>on</strong>s are critical to providing the organisati<strong>on</strong>al structures and<br />

processes necessary for effective management of voluntary codes including their<br />

73 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 26, p. 18.<br />

74 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 13, p. 4.<br />

75 Tasman Asia Pacific 2000, Analysis of market circumstances where industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to<br />

be most and least effective, p. 38.<br />

76 Ibid, p. 34.<br />

43


development, m<strong>on</strong>itoring and enforcement, and to ensure they provide net benefit<br />

and are not unduly restrictive of competiti<strong>on</strong>. 77<br />

Similarly, the c<strong>on</strong>sultant’s report stated that the development of a str<strong>on</strong>g industry<br />

associati<strong>on</strong> covering the majority of firms in a market can form a solid foundati<strong>on</strong> for<br />

effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. 78<br />

The Department of <strong>Industry</strong> Science and Resources also commented that a<br />

self-regulatory regime stands a greater chance of success if it is backed by a large and<br />

well structured industry associati<strong>on</strong> in a market with few industry participants.<br />

Primarily, this assists in regards to the costs associated with establishing and<br />

maintaining regimes; ensuring broad participati<strong>on</strong>; and issues of enforcement,<br />

including penalties and sancti<strong>on</strong>s. It noted that where no large industry associati<strong>on</strong><br />

exists, costs would appear to be a prohibiting factor in developing and administering<br />

a regime. 79<br />

Insurance Enquiries and Complaints Limited submitted that its scheme and the<br />

General Insurance Code are effective because of the Australia wide commitment from<br />

the industry and the Insurance Council of Australia. It submitted that all industry<br />

members selling pers<strong>on</strong>al lines insurance are involved, as are c<strong>on</strong>sumers,<br />

policyholders, c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups, Federal Government and the Insurance Council.<br />

There is a high level of industry ‘ownership’ of the code and the scheme, in other<br />

words a high level of participati<strong>on</strong> in the setting up, funding and <strong>on</strong>going<br />

development of them. 80<br />

On the other hand, the Department of Health and Aged Care commented that a<br />

challenge for self-regulatory schemes is where there is a lack of effective industry<br />

associati<strong>on</strong>s or where industry associati<strong>on</strong>s misrepresent industry members, or<br />

where there is limited commitment to a Code within the industry. 81<br />

Micro Business Network commented that those businesses in the micro business<br />

sector (including home-based businesses) that are not part of an industry associati<strong>on</strong><br />

would find it difficult to regulate because they have few resources and work l<strong>on</strong>g<br />

hours with often very little capital. It commented that microbusinesses operate in<br />

every industry but are difficult to target. 82<br />

ASIC also noted that the need for a str<strong>on</strong>g industry associati<strong>on</strong> may be reduced when<br />

the self-regulatory scheme has a ‘functi<strong>on</strong>al’ focus rather than instituti<strong>on</strong>al coverage.<br />

For example, a code of c<strong>on</strong>duct that covers similar products or services regardless of<br />

the instituti<strong>on</strong>s that offer such products may provide a more commercial basis for<br />

77 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 30, p. 3.<br />

78 Tasman Asia Pacific 2000, Analysis of market circumstances where industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to<br />

be most and least effective, p. 36.<br />

79 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 31, p. 22.<br />

80 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 8, p. 3.<br />

81 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 44, pp. 12-13.<br />

82 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 2, p. 1.<br />

44


membership than that which derives from a comm<strong>on</strong> industry perspective. That is,<br />

the comm<strong>on</strong> interest and commitment may be driven by a desire to meet appropriate<br />

market standards rather than the desire to meet the industry associati<strong>on</strong>’s<br />

requirements. 83<br />

The ability and willingness of industry to organise itself collectively dem<strong>on</strong>strates a<br />

capacity to undertake self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. An active industry associati<strong>on</strong> and/or industry<br />

commitment is most likely to lead to industry participants meeting the schemes’<br />

objectives.<br />

Cohesive industry<br />

An industry envir<strong>on</strong>ment where there is a cohesive industry with industry<br />

participants committed to achieving their goals is most likely to administer effective<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The Department of Health and Aged Care commented that a challenge for<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is where there is diversity within the industry (such as the private<br />

health sector) and industry members have diverging rather than c<strong>on</strong>verging<br />

interests. The Department was c<strong>on</strong>scious, however, that this may be addressed<br />

through structured and cooperative educati<strong>on</strong> strategies. 84<br />

The Associati<strong>on</strong> of Superannuati<strong>on</strong> Funds Australia commented that in order for<br />

effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> it is important to have relatively homogeneous objectives<br />

and cultures within the industry to reach c<strong>on</strong>sensus. 85 Similarly, the Instituti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

Engineers commented that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> requires extensive community and<br />

business educati<strong>on</strong>, and requires a commitment from all industry players to work<br />

effectively. 86<br />

The Investment and Financial Services Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that industry based<br />

complaints schemes rely heavily <strong>on</strong> the commitment of industry for their success in<br />

resolving c<strong>on</strong>sumer complaints and building c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence. A sense of<br />

‘ownership’ <strong>on</strong> the part of industry participants is essential to maintenance of this<br />

commitment and to retenti<strong>on</strong> by schemes of their self-regulatory character and<br />

effectiveness. 87<br />

Competitive market<br />

Competitive markets may be more c<strong>on</strong>ducive to more effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. In a<br />

more competitive market, participants are most likely to be committed to it to<br />

differentiate their products, or in fear of losing market share.<br />

83 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 8.<br />

84 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 44, p. 12.<br />

85 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 22, p. 3.<br />

86 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 26, p. 23.<br />

87 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 41, p. 4.<br />

45


For example, the NRMA commented that the combinati<strong>on</strong> of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> and<br />

competitive market forces creates a str<strong>on</strong>g incentive for companies to comply with,<br />

and in many cases exceed, the levels of customer service and other c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s that<br />

are specified in self-regulatory codes of practice. N<strong>on</strong>-compliance with the codes by a<br />

particular company could see it lose market share to competitors. 88<br />

NRMA commented that the main markets that it operates in, namely general<br />

insurance and financial services, are characterised by intense competiti<strong>on</strong> between a<br />

significant number of industry participants, and this creates a str<strong>on</strong>g incentive for<br />

companies to use adherence to codes as a marketing tool. It submitted that<br />

competiti<strong>on</strong> is also becoming more intense as new distributi<strong>on</strong> channels such as<br />

e-commerce emerge. 89<br />

Similarly, ASIC commented that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is more likely to be effective in a<br />

competitive market, as it will lessen the risk of such regulati<strong>on</strong> becoming an<br />

anti-competitive structure. 90 However, as noted above, this may also mean that the<br />

achievement of industry comm<strong>on</strong> interest can be more difficult.<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>sultant’s report also commented that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> tends to be more<br />

effective in those markets where there are relatively large numbers of competitive<br />

firms producing relatively homogeneous products. In such markets, firms can reap<br />

significant ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale by grouping together to self-regulate the activities of<br />

those firms within that group that impose costs <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumers, other firms within<br />

that group and the wider community. In additi<strong>on</strong>, because of the homogeneous<br />

nature of the product there is a much greater probability that the external costs<br />

generated by <strong>on</strong>e firm will adversely affect the sales of other firms producing those<br />

goods. 91<br />

On the other hand, the <strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sidered that<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> works well when there is a small number of large players (such as<br />

banking or insurance) as opposed to a large number of small players (financial<br />

planners). 92<br />

Similarly, during <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s some industry associati<strong>on</strong>s commented<br />

that fewer people or str<strong>on</strong>g leadership makes it easier to self-regulate as industries<br />

can get the level of detail they desire rather than having generic codes. 93<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>sultant’s report noted that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is less likely to be effective in those<br />

markets that are dominated by a very small number of firms due to the existence of<br />

88 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 7, p. 3.<br />

89 Ibid.<br />

90 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 9.<br />

91 Tasman Asia Pacific 2000, Analysis of market circumstances where industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to<br />

be most and least effective, p. 31.<br />

92 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 16, p. 1.<br />

93 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s with <strong>Australian</strong> Business Limited and the Fund Raising Institute,<br />

Sydney, 30 November 1999.<br />

46


large ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale in producti<strong>on</strong>. In these markets, the firms are more likely to<br />

share a comm<strong>on</strong> interest in using self-regulati<strong>on</strong> as a means of reducing, rather than<br />

increasing, the amount of competiti<strong>on</strong> between firms. In fact, in such cases, the<br />

ACCC is likely to c<strong>on</strong>sider such self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to be anti-competitive. 94<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in a competitive market with<br />

homogeneous products is most likely to produce effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Mature industry<br />

Maturity in the market may be another factor underpinning the effectiveness of<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that a more mature industry with<br />

established players may be more willing and able to participate in self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

For example, the <strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that voluntary<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can have little effect where there are ‘cowboys’ who are not prepared<br />

to participate. It argued that in the telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s industry, there are some<br />

companies who participate in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> and an increasing number of smaller<br />

players who do not. Again, it is a comparatively recently deregulated market. It<br />

argued that c<strong>on</strong>sumers using these companies have limited access to redress and do<br />

not enjoy adequate c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong>. 95<br />

However, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that it depends <strong>on</strong> what self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is trying<br />

to achieve. For example, a new industry may develop a self-regulatory scheme to<br />

develop c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence.<br />

Generally, a more mature industry with established players may be more willing and<br />

able to participate in self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>sumer interests<br />

Wider community awareness<br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be most effective where firms recognise that their future<br />

viability depends not <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong> their relati<strong>on</strong>ship with their current customers and<br />

shareholders, but also <strong>on</strong> the wider community.<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>sultant’s report submitted that many medium to larger firms now recognise<br />

that their l<strong>on</strong>ger term profitability and viability, and their potential to attract new<br />

customers and investors, does not depend solely <strong>on</strong> how they are viewed by their<br />

current customers and shareholders. It also depends <strong>on</strong> how their activities are<br />

viewed by the wider community and the government, who may have a significant<br />

94 Tasman Asia Pacific 2000, Analysis of market circumstances where industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to<br />

be most and least effective, p. 31.<br />

95 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 16, p. 1.<br />

47


influence <strong>on</strong> their future sales, sources of funds, profitability and the regulatory<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment. As a result, those firms are investing c<strong>on</strong>siderable amounts of time and<br />

m<strong>on</strong>ey in developing their reputati<strong>on</strong>s as socially resp<strong>on</strong>sible corporati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Introducing self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can be an important factor in improving their corporate<br />

image. 96<br />

The report observed that some self-regulatory codes not <strong>on</strong>ly try to improve market<br />

efficiency, but also seek to achieve a number of social welfare objectives. For<br />

example, the accountant’s Code of Professi<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>duct not <strong>on</strong>ly requires that<br />

members must safeguard the interests of their clients and employers, but also that<br />

they must not be in c<strong>on</strong>flict with duties owed to the community and its laws. 97 The<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that the failure of firms to act in a manner c<strong>on</strong>sistent with<br />

society’s broad social objectives can have a damaging effect <strong>on</strong> their overall<br />

reputati<strong>on</strong> and profitability, and that this provides a real incentive to implement<br />

effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Incentives to make self-regulati<strong>on</strong> effective<br />

For industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to be effective, there needs to be some vested interests or<br />

incentives to make it so. In other words, generally self-regulati<strong>on</strong> needs to be in the<br />

self-interest of industry to not <strong>on</strong>ly occur, but also to be effective. The more<br />

incentives for businesses to make self-regulati<strong>on</strong> work, then the more chance that<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> will be effective in achieving improved market outcomes for<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

The C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Network commented that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> will<br />

work when there is a substantial identity of interests with comm<strong>on</strong> benefit between<br />

carriers and an equal bargaining power of parties. It gave the example of ‘end to end’<br />

network performance (quality of ph<strong>on</strong>e call of both ends will be the same) working<br />

well because every<strong>on</strong>e has a comm<strong>on</strong> benefit. 98<br />

During the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s, the Financial Services C<strong>on</strong>sumer Policy Centre<br />

commented that there were three reas<strong>on</strong>s why industries self-regulate, namely:<br />

1. threat of Government regulati<strong>on</strong>;<br />

2. promoti<strong>on</strong>al opportunity; and/or<br />

3. a means for product differentiati<strong>on</strong>. 99<br />

96 Tasman Asia Pacific 2000, Analysis of market circumstances where industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to<br />

be most and least effective, p. 24.<br />

97 Ibid, p. 24.<br />

98 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Network, Sydney, 30 November<br />

1999.<br />

99 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the Financial Services C<strong>on</strong>sumer Policy Centre, as part of a<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer group roundtable discussi<strong>on</strong>, Sydney, 30 November 1999.<br />

48


The <strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong> was of a similar mind, submitting that there<br />

may be a ‘carrot’, such as the opportunity to differentiate a company by adhering to a<br />

code (especially if there are ‘cowboys’ in the market), or a ‘stick’ (such as industry,<br />

media or c<strong>on</strong>sumer pressure). 100<br />

ASIC was of the view that comm<strong>on</strong> interest will usually involve a mix of ‘positive’<br />

and ‘negative’ incentives. An example of positive comm<strong>on</strong> interest is a desire to<br />

improve professi<strong>on</strong>alism in the industry. ASIC argued that improving c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

c<strong>on</strong>fidence can have both positive and negative elements. Most self-regulatory<br />

schemes also seek to improve c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence where it is currently inadequate<br />

such as in areas of new technology or where there have been problematic industry<br />

practices. 101<br />

ASIC also submitted that negative self-interest can include the desire to avoid<br />

government, which may be an explicit ‘threat’ via direct government pressure or an<br />

implicit ‘threat’ arising out of the general directi<strong>on</strong> of government policy reforms. At<br />

its best, this involves a genuine commitment to self-regulati<strong>on</strong> that will deliver<br />

market improvements in a cost-effective manner. ASIC noted that, in the past,<br />

comprehensive self-regulatory schemes have generally been developed <strong>on</strong>ly where<br />

there has been a real threat of government or regulator interventi<strong>on</strong>. 102<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>sultant’s report noted that ‘external’ costs and benefits may not be taken into<br />

account by firms and c<strong>on</strong>sumers when determining how much they should produce<br />

and c<strong>on</strong>sume. The effectiveness of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> depends <strong>on</strong> the extent to which<br />

firms have the incentive and the ability to ‘avoid’ external costs or ‘internalise’<br />

external benefits and costs. 103<br />

Where there is no or little comm<strong>on</strong> interest, then it is harder to make self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

work. For example, PowerTel commented that <strong>on</strong>e element that must be kept outside<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is where significant c<strong>on</strong>flicts of interest are likely to result from the<br />

self-regulatory process. 104<br />

During <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s, it was evident that telecommunicati<strong>on</strong> codes that<br />

deal with commercial interest are being developed a lot faster than c<strong>on</strong>sumer codes,<br />

because of the self-interest by carriers.<br />

The Service Providers <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> (SPAN) commented that instances<br />

abound where the rate of progress <strong>on</strong> important regulatory/self-regulatory<br />

initiatives has fallen well below industry aspirati<strong>on</strong>s and expectati<strong>on</strong>s. Examples<br />

dem<strong>on</strong>strate that a self-regulatory model is ill suited to any situati<strong>on</strong> where there are<br />

100 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 16, p. 1.<br />

101 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 8.<br />

102 Ibid.<br />

103 Tasman Asia Pacific 2000, Analysis of market circumstances where industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to<br />

be most and least effective, p. 18.<br />

104 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 9, p. 1.<br />

49


c<strong>on</strong>flicting commercial interests to be rec<strong>on</strong>ciled and particularly where the<br />

bargaining power and informati<strong>on</strong> available to the parties are unbalanced. 105<br />

SPAN commented that reas<strong>on</strong>s for delay include the natural tendency of engineering<br />

and legal/regulatory people, who make up the self-regulatory workforce, to want to<br />

tease out all elements of technical complexity and risk in the process of code<br />

formulati<strong>on</strong>. This attitude is understandable, but is tempered in normal business<br />

c<strong>on</strong>duct by the imperative of targets and deadlines set by executive management to<br />

achieve goals such as time-to-market advantage over competiti<strong>on</strong>. That discipline is<br />

either absent or given insufficient weight within the self-regulatory framework.<br />

SPAN noted that a further reas<strong>on</strong> for delay often quoted is the attitude of incumbent<br />

operators whose commercial interests are to perpetuate the status quo as l<strong>on</strong>g as<br />

possible. 106<br />

The C<strong>on</strong>sumer’s Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Network was c<strong>on</strong>cerned that, often, quality of<br />

service and profitability do not go hand-in-hand. 107<br />

For industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to be effective, then there needs to be incentives to make<br />

it work. The more cohesive an industry is with incentives to make self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

work, then the more chance that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> will be effective and meet its<br />

objectives.<br />

Market incentives<br />

The existence of market incentives to comply with self-regulatory schemes are most<br />

likely to increase the effectiveness of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. An industry envir<strong>on</strong>ment where<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> may be most effective is where there is voluntary participati<strong>on</strong> with<br />

effective sancti<strong>on</strong>s and incentives to ensure that there is little scope for<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-participants in the scheme to enjoy the benefits.<br />

For example, the Department of <strong>Industry</strong>, Science and Resources commented that<br />

voluntary participati<strong>on</strong>—backed by str<strong>on</strong>g incentives to participate—appears to<br />

provide a str<strong>on</strong>ger framework and higher degree of success, independent of the size<br />

of the industry associati<strong>on</strong>. Whereas, it commented that mandatory participati<strong>on</strong> and<br />

subsequent issues of compliance, enforcement, penalties and/or sancti<strong>on</strong>s appear to<br />

depend primarily <strong>on</strong> the size and strength of the industry associati<strong>on</strong>. 108<br />

The Instituti<strong>on</strong> of Engineers also commented that effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> requires<br />

not <strong>on</strong>ly standards or codes of practice, but also effective mechanisms for dealing<br />

with complaints with these codes. 109<br />

105 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 25, p. 3.<br />

106 Ibid.<br />

107 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with CTN, Sydney, 30 November 1999.<br />

108 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 31, p. 22.<br />

109 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 26, p. 15.<br />

50


The Associati<strong>on</strong> of Superannuati<strong>on</strong> Funds Australia commented that for<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to be effective industry requires effective enforcement and sancti<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

for example the standards need to be well known and/or branded. If an industry<br />

member fails to meet these standards then some sancti<strong>on</strong> is required (e.g. fine,<br />

‘shaming’ or corrective advertising restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> licence to operate). It argued that<br />

such enforcement also requires/assumes that effective complaint procedures are<br />

easily accessible for c<strong>on</strong>sumers. 110<br />

During the c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>on</strong>e organisati<strong>on</strong> commented that public shaming is like<br />

being ‘dumped into custard — it is a soft landing, but it sticks’. 111<br />

Similarly, NRMA commented that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> also functi<strong>on</strong>s effectively in<br />

industries where brand name image and customer loyalty are important<br />

determinants of market share and profitability. Any damage to brand reputati<strong>on</strong><br />

through n<strong>on</strong>-compliance with a code of practice could be very costly to restore. 112<br />

On the other hand, the Motor Trades Associati<strong>on</strong> of Australia commented that<br />

industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> has not been effective in relati<strong>on</strong> to Franchising and Oilcode<br />

because sancti<strong>on</strong>s are ineffective because offending parties can simply ‘drop out’ of<br />

the scheme and c<strong>on</strong>tinue the offending behaviour. It argued that if there is no penalty<br />

or detriment for n<strong>on</strong>-participati<strong>on</strong>, then many will questi<strong>on</strong> why they should join. 113<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumer’s Associati<strong>on</strong> argued that there is need for government<br />

underpinning of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. It c<strong>on</strong>sidered that the involvement of ASIC in<br />

approving codes and dispute schemes, as part of the new regulatory framework for<br />

the financial sector being introduced as part of the Corporate Law Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Reform<br />

Program, will ensure that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> ‘best practice’ principles become legislative<br />

requirements. 114<br />

The existence of market incentives and effective sancti<strong>on</strong>s is most likely to increase<br />

the effectiveness of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, where participants will comply more with<br />

schemes, which it turn, can improve market outcomes for c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

Adequate industry coverage<br />

An important element of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is coverage. The extent to which industry<br />

participants are prepared to sign up to a self-regulatory scheme will affect their<br />

ability to provide effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. Where a scheme has a high level of<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer recogniti<strong>on</strong>, to the point where c<strong>on</strong>sumers will favour that scheme, then<br />

the scheme is most likely to be effective. There then may be market pressures for<br />

other industry participants to join the scheme.<br />

110 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 22, p. 3.<br />

111 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the <strong>Australian</strong> Press Council, Sydney, 1 December 1999.<br />

112 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 7, p. 3.<br />

113 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 1, p. 1.<br />

114 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 16, p. 1.<br />

51


A significant number of organisati<strong>on</strong>s commented that wide coverage was an<br />

important element of good practice. For example, the Financial <strong>Industry</strong> Complaints<br />

Service c<strong>on</strong>sidered that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly works where the whole segment of a<br />

particular industry is covered by <strong>on</strong>e scheme and rules are uniform. 115 Similarly, the<br />

Associati<strong>on</strong> of Superannuati<strong>on</strong> Funds Australia commented that for self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

to be effective, then it is necessary to have close to 100 per cent coverage of industry<br />

participants. 116<br />

The Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman stated that its success has been due<br />

to its ability to maintain an appropriate level of c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> in a rapidly<br />

changing competitive envir<strong>on</strong>ment, with more than substantial coverage of the<br />

telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s industry. A measure of the extent of this coverage is evident by<br />

the increase in membership from three members at its incepti<strong>on</strong> to over 900 members<br />

at the date of its submissi<strong>on</strong>. 117<br />

Further, ASIC commented that wide industry coverage may be easier to achieve in<br />

an industry with fewer and larger organisati<strong>on</strong>s as the problem of ‘free riders’ is less<br />

apparent. It stated that free rider problems can be of two broad types:<br />

¾ <strong>Industry</strong> members may choose not to join the self-regulatory scheme at all. This<br />

can be a particular problem in those industries characterised by a large number<br />

of firms including many smaller firms or individual practiti<strong>on</strong>ers; and<br />

¾ <strong>Industry</strong> members may join the self-regulatory scheme, but choose not to<br />

properly adhere to the agreed rules.<br />

ASIC argued that in both cases the free riding firm may gain competitive advantages<br />

by enjoying the public benefits of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> while not bearing its costs. 118<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>sultant’s report also submitted that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is more likely to be<br />

effective where there is limited scope for adversely affected individuals and firms to<br />

‘free ride’ <strong>on</strong> the benefits of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. 119<br />

The effectiveness of any self-regulatory scheme will <strong>on</strong>ly be as good as the extent of<br />

its coverage. The extent to which industry participants are prepared to sign up to a<br />

self-regulatory scheme will affect the ability of them to provide effective<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

115 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 15, p. 3.<br />

116 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 22, p. 3.<br />

117 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 21, p. 8.<br />

118 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 9.<br />

119 Tasman Asia Pacific 2000, Analysis of market circumstances where industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to<br />

be most and least effective, p. 38.<br />

52


Cost advantages and/or increased flexibility<br />

An industry envir<strong>on</strong>ment where there are cost advantages and/or increased<br />

flexibility in developing and maintaining self-regulati<strong>on</strong> compared with government<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> or the court system can underpin more effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. Cost<br />

advantages, for both business and c<strong>on</strong>sumers, could include less formal mechanisms<br />

such as quick complaints handling and redress mechanisms.<br />

The Federati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Australian</strong> Radio Broadcasters stated that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is usually<br />

faster and less expensive as well as more flexible and up-to-date than Government<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> because industry has a better understanding of the problems and what<br />

their realistic soluti<strong>on</strong>s are. 120<br />

Similarly with court costs, a number of organisati<strong>on</strong>s commented that self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

is quicker and cheaper. For example, the Financial <strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Service<br />

Limited stated that it is a fact that dispute schemes provide a cheaper service than the<br />

courts and hopefully greater c<strong>on</strong>sumer retenti<strong>on</strong> for the industry involved. 121<br />

Echoing these comments, the Investment and Financial Services Associati<strong>on</strong> stated<br />

that in the <strong>Australian</strong> financial services sector, dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes have<br />

evolved as cost-effective alternatives to litigati<strong>on</strong>. They have reduced pressure for<br />

Government interventi<strong>on</strong> in the industry, especially where such schemes have<br />

entailed complete market coverage. 122<br />

The Insurance Council of Australia commented that its self-regulatory initiatives<br />

have worked effectively because of the absence of any overlay of legalism or<br />

formality (such as an appeals process) which makes the Scheme accessible and<br />

attractive to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. 123<br />

NRMA commented that an envir<strong>on</strong>ment where an industry’s products and<br />

distributi<strong>on</strong> channels are undergoing c<strong>on</strong>tinual change is also better suited to<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> rather than formal government regulati<strong>on</strong>. This reflects the fact that<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> will generally be more flexible and adaptable to changing<br />

circumstances such as new technology and new products. The NRMA submitted that<br />

financial services is an example of an industry that is undergoing rapid and<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tinuous change. 124<br />

Where there are cost advantages and/or increased flexibility in developing and<br />

maintaining self-regulati<strong>on</strong> more effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> may be achieved.<br />

120 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 35, p. 1.<br />

121 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 15, p. 3.<br />

122 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 41, p. 2.<br />

123 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 18, p. 6.<br />

124 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 7, p. 3.<br />

53


Chapter 6<br />

Good practice and cost-effective<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> methods<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> is to inquire and report <strong>on</strong> best practice and cost-effective<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> methods and approaches.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> believes there is no single ‘best practice’ model for self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

because a successful model depends <strong>on</strong> particular market characteristics and needs<br />

to be designed accordingly. However, it is possible to identify critical elements of<br />

schemes which individually or collectively have underpinned successfully operating<br />

schemes. A number of these elements are identified through the report.<br />

Good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can be understood as improving market outcomes<br />

for c<strong>on</strong>sumers at the lowest cost to businesses. A particular self-regulatory scheme<br />

may not be appropriate in circumstances where other forms of regulati<strong>on</strong> are able to<br />

provide better outcomes at a lower cost. For example, the costs involved with a<br />

complex customer dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanism may not be justified if the scheme<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly receives a few complaints per year. Further, the costs involved in administering<br />

such a scheme may be translated into higher prices for c<strong>on</strong>sumers so, in this case,<br />

would not c<strong>on</strong>stitute a better market outcome for either business or c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

55


Principles<br />

¾ Good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> involves addressing industry specific<br />

problems and objectives.<br />

¾ The type of self-regulatory scheme should be the effective minimum soluti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong><br />

16. C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> between industry, c<strong>on</strong>sumers and Government can help ensure<br />

that specific problems and social policy objectives can be identified and<br />

addressed.<br />

Coverage and publicity<br />

17. Increased industry coverage of schemes ensures that the benefits from<br />

standards of practice in schemes flow to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. Wide coverage also<br />

ensures that c<strong>on</strong>sumers can identify self-regulatory schemes.<br />

18. Clarity in the schemes’ documentati<strong>on</strong> can help industry understand their<br />

obligati<strong>on</strong>s and assist dispute schemes interpret legal rights. Clarity can also<br />

help c<strong>on</strong>sumers understand their rights.<br />

19. C<strong>on</strong>sumer awareness of schemes ensures that c<strong>on</strong>sumers understand their<br />

rights and reap the benefits from standards of practice set by schemes.<br />

Schemes are encouraged to make use of new technologies such as the<br />

Internet, by making complaints cost free to the c<strong>on</strong>sumer, through writing<br />

sample letters of complaint, through taking oral complaints where possible,<br />

and through transferring complainants between schemes where possible.<br />

20. <strong>Industry</strong> awareness of schemes is needed to make sure industry participants<br />

understand their obligati<strong>on</strong>s and, where appropriate, understand the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences of failing to abide by these obligati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Administrati<strong>on</strong><br />

21. A good administrative body can identify issues, collect data, m<strong>on</strong>itor the<br />

scheme, enhance credibility and ensure compliance costs are at an effective<br />

minimum level.<br />

22. Data collecti<strong>on</strong> by an industry scheme is a valuable tool in identifying<br />

systemic issues and allows industry to address these problems, which in turn,<br />

can improve market outcomes for both businesses and c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

23. As c<strong>on</strong>sumers cannot guard against specific industry problems that they do<br />

not know exist, transparency in schemes is an important mechanism to ensure<br />

credibility and accountability.<br />

56


Dispute procedures and sancti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

24. <strong>Industry</strong> adherence to self-regulatory schemes is essential to ensure that the<br />

benefits flowing from the standards of practice set by schemes are passed<br />

<strong>on</strong>to the c<strong>on</strong>sumer.<br />

25. Where the standard of c<strong>on</strong>duct has been breached, self-regulatory schemes<br />

should incorporate complaint handling and dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms to<br />

provide appropriate redress to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. The appropriate redress<br />

mechanism will depend <strong>on</strong> the nature of the specific problem and the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences of n<strong>on</strong>-compliance.<br />

26. A range of sancti<strong>on</strong>s can be used by industry in order to achieve compliance<br />

depending <strong>on</strong> the nature of the specific problem and c<strong>on</strong>sequences of<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-compliance. The severity of the sancti<strong>on</strong> should depend <strong>on</strong> the<br />

seriousness of the breach.<br />

27. <strong>Industry</strong> needs to manage the risk of any anti-competitive practices in<br />

schemes, particularly where sancti<strong>on</strong>s are involved.<br />

M<strong>on</strong>itoring and reviewing<br />

28. M<strong>on</strong>itoring of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is essential to ensure that it is still relevant to the<br />

industry addressing specific problems and improving market outcomes. In<br />

this c<strong>on</strong>text, reviews and annual reporting are useful tools for m<strong>on</strong>itoring<br />

schemes and can also assist in the transparency and accountability of<br />

schemes. Preferably, reviews should be periodic, independent and the results<br />

made publicly available.<br />

Cost-effectiveness<br />

29. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> comes at a cost, in administrati<strong>on</strong>, promoti<strong>on</strong> and compliance.<br />

However, self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can be cheaper (in terms of compliance costs) and<br />

more flexible than Government regulati<strong>on</strong> and the court system. Ultimately,<br />

the c<strong>on</strong>sumer bears the cost of regulati<strong>on</strong> in most cases.<br />

30. Any funding arrangement for self-regulati<strong>on</strong> should be transparent and<br />

designed so as not to put businesses at a competitive disadvantage through<br />

excessive compliance costs.<br />

57


Good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> is very broad and covers guidelines, quality management systems,<br />

standards, codes, dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes etc. Although there is no <strong>on</strong>e model for<br />

good self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that there are elements of good practice<br />

that are c<strong>on</strong>sistent am<strong>on</strong>gst schemes.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong><br />

Addressing specific problems and objectives<br />

The form of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> adopted by industry should be the effective minimum<br />

soluti<strong>on</strong> to the specific problem to minimise compliance costs for business.<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Chamber of Commerce and <strong>Industry</strong> argued that self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

allows industry to resp<strong>on</strong>d to c<strong>on</strong>cerns raised by c<strong>on</strong>sumers and identify soluti<strong>on</strong>s to<br />

problems by utilising the resources and expertise unavailable to Government. It<br />

commented that under self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, industry (often through associati<strong>on</strong>s) could<br />

assume resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for c<strong>on</strong>cerns raised by the community and is able to interact<br />

directly with stakeholders to resolve the problem. 125<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Chamber of Commerce and <strong>Industry</strong> also submitted that<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> enables commerce and industry to resp<strong>on</strong>d more efficiently and<br />

effectively to the changing c<strong>on</strong>cerns of c<strong>on</strong>sumers. It will also empower users,<br />

whether business or householders, through the market-mechanisms. 126 In the<br />

telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s industry, the Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman<br />

commented that good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> involves the ability to address<br />

specific problems which affect c<strong>on</strong>sumers. Reduced to the most basic issue, the<br />

problems facing c<strong>on</strong>sumers are those that involve the transiti<strong>on</strong> from a previously<br />

m<strong>on</strong>opolistic envir<strong>on</strong>ment in telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s to <strong>on</strong>e of open, but still regulated,<br />

competiti<strong>on</strong>. 127<br />

The Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman commented that c<strong>on</strong>sumers have<br />

been faced with difficulties of choice not <strong>on</strong>ly am<strong>on</strong>gst many more providers, but<br />

also am<strong>on</strong>gst many new services and products with differing prices, as well as with<br />

relatively new technologies such as mobile communicati<strong>on</strong>s and the Internet. These<br />

difficulties have c<strong>on</strong>tributed to disputes about bills — the single highest area of<br />

complaint to their scheme. It argued that it has resolved these types of complaints<br />

125 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 27, p. 5.<br />

126 Ibid.<br />

127 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 21, p. 9.<br />

58


and has also highlighted systemic problems within industry forums and individual<br />

members. 128<br />

Similarly, the Federati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Australian</strong> Commercial Televisi<strong>on</strong> Stati<strong>on</strong>s submitted<br />

that the industry c<strong>on</strong>siders that the code approach is more effective and efficient than<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> in achieving public interest objectives, in terms of flexibility,<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness to community views, transparency and ease of use by stati<strong>on</strong>s and<br />

viewers alike. 129<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong><br />

As touched <strong>on</strong> above, although self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the resp<strong>on</strong>sibility of industry, both<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers and the Government are stakeholders. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> is not <strong>on</strong>ly important to ensure credibility of a scheme, but c<strong>on</strong>sumers<br />

can help identify specific problems within an industry and Government can identify<br />

social or public policy objectives.<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Chamber of Commerce and <strong>Industry</strong> submitted that a key element of<br />

managing self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the establishment of structures involving stakeholders to<br />

facilitate resoluti<strong>on</strong>. 130<br />

The ACCC argued that if codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct/self-regulati<strong>on</strong> are going to be accepted<br />

by governments and the public at large, then credibility with stakeholders is<br />

absolutely vital, because <strong>on</strong>ly with such credibility will there be public acceptance of<br />

the code or an industry-based scheme and commitment to it by the appropriate<br />

regulators. It argued that to have any credibility at all there needs to be c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong><br />

with the appropriate c<strong>on</strong>sumer/community/user groups and appropriate<br />

regulatory/government agencies, as well as industry members. 131<br />

During the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s, a number of schemes commented that they<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sult with c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups. 132 The Financial <strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Scheme<br />

commented that some industry associati<strong>on</strong>s offer forums for c<strong>on</strong>sumers but most<br />

meet with recognised c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups. 133<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that it has<br />

close relati<strong>on</strong>ships with the Therapeutic Goods Administrati<strong>on</strong> and the ACCC. In<br />

additi<strong>on</strong>, it maintains close relati<strong>on</strong>ships with prescribers and allied organisati<strong>on</strong>s to<br />

m<strong>on</strong>itor the code and to seek comment and suggesti<strong>on</strong>s for its improvement.<br />

128 Ibid.<br />

129 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 34, p. 10.<br />

130 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 27, p. 12.<br />

131 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 42, p. 25.<br />

132 For example, <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s with the <strong>Australian</strong> Banking <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman and<br />

Insurance Brokers’ Dispute Facility, Melbourne, 22 November 1999.<br />

133 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 15, p. 4.<br />

59


C<strong>on</strong>sumers are also viewed by the Associati<strong>on</strong> as a key stakeholder with the<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Health Forum being represented <strong>on</strong> the Code of C<strong>on</strong>duct Committees. 134<br />

Standards Australia stated that it uses the internati<strong>on</strong>ally accepted principle of<br />

preparing standards that involve transparency and c<strong>on</strong>sensus. This includes:<br />

¾ the use of committees to represent all relevant stakeholders;<br />

¾ the issue of drafts for public comment (usually for 60 days); and<br />

¾ approval for publicati<strong>on</strong> by a c<strong>on</strong>sensus of all relevant stakeholders. 135<br />

Similarly, the <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s Authority commented that when<br />

assessing a code for registrati<strong>on</strong> it must be satisfied that c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> has been<br />

undertaken with the public, the industry, the ACCC, Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong><br />

Ombudsman, a c<strong>on</strong>sumer representative organisati<strong>on</strong>, and for privacy codes, the<br />

Privacy Commissi<strong>on</strong>er. 136<br />

However, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that c<strong>on</strong>sumer interests are typically diverse and<br />

highly dispersed in comparis<strong>on</strong> to industry interests. ASIC commented that because<br />

of this it would usually be more difficult for c<strong>on</strong>sumers to independently generate<br />

sufficient resources and expertise to provide effective input to the full range of<br />

self-regulatory mechanisms without additi<strong>on</strong>al assistance. Importantly, ASIC argued<br />

that such input is required not <strong>on</strong>ly during the development of self-regulatory<br />

mechanisms, but also during the <strong>on</strong>going life of such mechanisms to ensure adequate<br />

accountability, appropriate independence and c<strong>on</strong>tinuing relevance. 137<br />

Similarly, the <strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that codes and<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> are drafted by the supply side of a market. <strong>Industry</strong> has the resources<br />

to create complex analysis and reports. Whereas, it argued the demand side, as<br />

represented by the c<strong>on</strong>sumer movement, have fewer resources to provide the same<br />

level of input. So while the opportunity to c<strong>on</strong>sult is there, the means are limited. 138<br />

NSW Legal Aid also commented that these activities are labour intensive. 139<br />

The Office of Small Business also argued that any code of c<strong>on</strong>duct or self-regulatory<br />

mechanism needs to have genuine small business representati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> code councils (or<br />

similar style bodies). It argued that there is an equal need to ensure the same<br />

representati<strong>on</strong> for small business as for other affected groups such as c<strong>on</strong>sumers. 140<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> supports the propositi<strong>on</strong> that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> should be developed and<br />

maintained in partnership between industry, the regulator and c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

134 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 10, p. 1.<br />

135 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 13, p. 2.<br />

136 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 17, p. 4.<br />

137 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 13.<br />

138 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 16, p. 2.<br />

139 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 24, p. 6.<br />

140 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 38, p. 4.<br />

60


organisati<strong>on</strong>s. This partnership is essential to identify specific problems and to arrive<br />

at effective minimum soluti<strong>on</strong>s. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> also recognises the important role that<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups can play in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> development and growth. 141<br />

Coverage and publicity<br />

Adequate coverage<br />

An important element of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is coverage. 142 The extent to which an<br />

industry associati<strong>on</strong> represents the majority of industry participants affects the<br />

ability of the associati<strong>on</strong> to deliver effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. If schemes do not have<br />

wide industry coverage, then fewer c<strong>on</strong>sumers will enjoy improved market<br />

outcomes. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that the effectiveness of any self-regulatory<br />

scheme will <strong>on</strong>ly be as good as the extent of its coverage.<br />

Clarity<br />

An industry seeking to self-regulate must be able to establish certain standards of<br />

c<strong>on</strong>duct which members will support. This will ensure that members understand<br />

their obligati<strong>on</strong>s and c<strong>on</strong>sumers will be aware of their rights. As noted above, the<br />

standards will differ according to the specific problem and the industry c<strong>on</strong>cerned.<br />

During <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s, some organisati<strong>on</strong>s commented that self-regulatory<br />

schemes need to be written in a plain language that both c<strong>on</strong>sumers and industry can<br />

understand. 143<br />

In relati<strong>on</strong> to codes, the ACCC argued that in order to be accepted by all stakeholders<br />

it is important for the code to be drafted in a technically legal sense but it is even<br />

more important for the language to be plain and understandable to all of its readers.<br />

Clarity in the document will instil more c<strong>on</strong>fidence and certainty whilst any<br />

ambiguity or vagueness will militate against acceptance, support and compliance.<br />

This is particularly important in the area of understanding obligati<strong>on</strong>s and allowing<br />

for enforcement. 144<br />

As suggested by the ACCC, the code should set out clearly stated reas<strong>on</strong>s why the<br />

code was established and what are the intended outcomes. To be effective in<br />

addressing c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>cerns a code needs to have rules which address comm<strong>on</strong><br />

complaints and c<strong>on</strong>cerns about industry practices and which set performance<br />

141 Chapter 7 — approaches to promoting and coordinating self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, looks at the role of<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups and Government in more detail.<br />

142 Chapter 5 indicates that if a scheme does not have adequate coverage, then it has little chance of<br />

being successful.<br />

143 For example, <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the Society of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Professi<strong>on</strong>als in<br />

Business, Canberra, 7 December 1999.<br />

144 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 42, p. 25.<br />

61


standards for participants. Such rules should address specific stated problems and<br />

not be written as broad general principles. 145<br />

As a general rule, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that standards in a self-regulatory scheme<br />

ought to be specific and written in a plain and easy to understand manner. This will<br />

ensure that c<strong>on</strong>sumers understand their rights and industries understand their<br />

obligati<strong>on</strong>s. Clarity in the documentati<strong>on</strong> will also assist dispute schemes interpret<br />

legal rights.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer awareness<br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> needs to be promoted and c<strong>on</strong>sumers need to be aware of various<br />

schemes. C<strong>on</strong>sumer awareness of schemes ensures that c<strong>on</strong>sumers understand their<br />

rights and know where to lodge complaints. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> believes that access to<br />

self-regulatory schemes is crucial.<br />

The Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Advisory Council commented that codes are<br />

invisible to certain c<strong>on</strong>sumers. In particular:<br />

¾ urban elderly women and men;<br />

¾ rural and remote families;<br />

¾ working parents who have no time;<br />

¾ people isolated in their own homes because of poverty or ill health;<br />

¾ people with low literacy and/or verbal skills;<br />

¾ people of working age dependent <strong>on</strong> Government support;<br />

¾ young people who have never had a full time job, permanent job; and<br />

¾ n<strong>on</strong>-English speaking people. 146<br />

It argued that an effective code would place the <strong>on</strong>us <strong>on</strong> the provider to make<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers aware that a code exists and an easy access point to provide all necessary<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> about the code. The <strong>on</strong>us to advise c<strong>on</strong>sumers should arise during the<br />

course of a relevant transacti<strong>on</strong>. 147<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong> stated that empowering c<strong>on</strong>sumers to<br />

interact with industry in a self-regulatory envir<strong>on</strong>ment is crucial. C<strong>on</strong>sumers need<br />

easy access to dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes and educati<strong>on</strong> about the requirements of<br />

industry codes, regardless of their literacy or financial background. It argued that<br />

145 Ibid.<br />

146 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 14, p. 4.<br />

147 Ibid.<br />

62


<strong>on</strong>e of the obvious areas that require improvement is in the provisi<strong>on</strong> of written<br />

evidence. For people of a low literacy level or n<strong>on</strong>-English speaking background this<br />

can be difficult. The Associati<strong>on</strong> recommended the provisi<strong>on</strong> of oral evidence and<br />

the use of new technologies to facilitate greater c<strong>on</strong>sumer educati<strong>on</strong> and access to<br />

dispute schemes. 148<br />

The Law Council of Australia argued that the suggesti<strong>on</strong> that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is for<br />

the benefit of c<strong>on</strong>sumers, as it keeps the prices of goods and services lower than<br />

would otherwise be possible, is <strong>on</strong>ly part of the equati<strong>on</strong>. It submitted that the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer must also have redress from an impartial umpire. Disadvantaged low<br />

income, poorly educated and foreign born c<strong>on</strong>sumers, who comprise a significant<br />

number of c<strong>on</strong>sumers, are not in a positi<strong>on</strong> to analyse the informati<strong>on</strong> or access legal<br />

and other representative systems to assess the informati<strong>on</strong> for them. 149<br />

Similarly, during the c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s held by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g>, other organisati<strong>on</strong>s raised<br />

the importance of c<strong>on</strong>sumer awareness of schemes and suggested the schemes<br />

should be user-friendly. However, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that equality in access is<br />

not just isolated to self-regulatory schemes ⎯ similar issues of access apply to the<br />

court system for example.<br />

The Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman scheme c<strong>on</strong>ducts regular two-year<br />

public awareness surveys, as well as biannual complaint satisfacti<strong>on</strong> surveys. It<br />

commented that their scheme has also paid attenti<strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>sumers from n<strong>on</strong>-English<br />

speaking backgrounds. There is also no cost to c<strong>on</strong>sumers accessing the scheme. The<br />

scheme has widely advertised 1800 Freecall and Freefax number and also accepts<br />

complaints <strong>on</strong>-line through its Website, as well as by mail and in pers<strong>on</strong>. 150<br />

The Federati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Australian</strong> Commercial Televisi<strong>on</strong> Stati<strong>on</strong>s commented that<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers with a disability may complain via the teleph<strong>on</strong>e or <strong>on</strong> an audio cassette<br />

in the first instance. It stated that there has been a c<strong>on</strong>siderable degree of public<br />

awareness of the Code over the six years of its operati<strong>on</strong>. This has been facilitated by<br />

<strong>on</strong>-air publicati<strong>on</strong> by stati<strong>on</strong>s. This has now been formalised in the revised Code. It<br />

commented that all stati<strong>on</strong>s must broadcast 360 <strong>on</strong>-air spots per year across all<br />

viewing z<strong>on</strong>es about the code and the complaint process. In additi<strong>on</strong>, they have<br />

established a nati<strong>on</strong>al ph<strong>on</strong>e hotline (a 1800 number) which provides informati<strong>on</strong><br />

about the code, how to make complaints and how to c<strong>on</strong>tact local stati<strong>on</strong>s. 151<br />

Throughout this report, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has stressed that c<strong>on</strong>sumer awareness is an<br />

important element of good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>sumer awareness of<br />

schemes ensures that c<strong>on</strong>sumers are aware of their rights. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises<br />

that schemes can encourage access by utilising technology such as web-sites, by<br />

making any complaints cost free to the c<strong>on</strong>sumer, through writing sample letters of<br />

148 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 16, p. 2.<br />

149 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 19, p. 8.<br />

150 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 21, p. 10.<br />

151 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 34, p. 8.<br />

63


complaint, through taking oral complaints where possible, and through transferring<br />

complainants between schemes where possible.<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> awareness<br />

As well as c<strong>on</strong>sumer awareness, industry members need to be aware of what they<br />

are supposed to be doing in terms of compliance. Raising industry awareness of<br />

schemes ensures that industry participants understand their obligati<strong>on</strong>s to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

The ACCC commented that in many cases a code fails to operate effectively, not<br />

because its principles and procedures are inadequate, but because employees or<br />

industry members are either unaware of the code or fail to follow it in day-to-day<br />

dealings. 152<br />

For example, to raise industry awareness, the <strong>Australian</strong> Subscripti<strong>on</strong> Televisi<strong>on</strong> and<br />

Radio Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that they undertake regular codes presentati<strong>on</strong>s to<br />

relevant staff of platforms, channels and call centres. It argued that it is of particular<br />

importance that, with the level of staff turnover in the call centres, that these<br />

presentati<strong>on</strong>s are c<strong>on</strong>ducted regularly. 153<br />

Similarly, the <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that it has<br />

undertaken a major industry educati<strong>on</strong> initiative to assist members in ensuring that<br />

their organisati<strong>on</strong>s comply with their code. It commented that this has taken the form<br />

of full-day Code Compliance Workshops across Australia that have, at the time of<br />

their submissi<strong>on</strong>, attracted over 200 of their members. 154<br />

Administrati<strong>on</strong><br />

Administrati<strong>on</strong><br />

Actually administering a self-regulatory scheme can be a task in itself. A good<br />

administrative body can identify specific problems in an industry, collect data,<br />

m<strong>on</strong>itor the scheme and enhance its credibility.<br />

The Department of <strong>Industry</strong>, Science and Resources commented that an aut<strong>on</strong>omous<br />

body with diverse stakeholder representati<strong>on</strong> should be tasked with m<strong>on</strong>itoring,<br />

maintaining and enforcing the regime. It is particularly important that such a body<br />

have resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for establishing and undertaking a c<strong>on</strong>tinuous review program to<br />

ensure the regime is a ‘living organism’. 155<br />

152 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 42, p. 27.<br />

153 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 39, p. 5.<br />

154 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 36, p. 4.<br />

155 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 31, p. 22.<br />

64


The Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Advisory Council argued that codes must<br />

have a ‘home’ and an administrati<strong>on</strong>. It noted that it has been said that <strong>on</strong>e of the key<br />

reas<strong>on</strong>s for the success of the General Insurance Code is that not <strong>on</strong>ly does it have a<br />

proper administrati<strong>on</strong> but also a Board of Directors comprised of insurance company<br />

Chief Executive Officers together with other major stakeholders. 156<br />

The ACCC commented that industry-based code schemes aimed at delivering fair<br />

trading outcomes need to c<strong>on</strong>tain appropriate c<strong>on</strong>sumer/user representati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the<br />

administrati<strong>on</strong> committee. In some instances, representati<strong>on</strong> by the appropriate<br />

regulatory authority <strong>on</strong> the code administrati<strong>on</strong> body can serve as a means of the<br />

regulatory body putting forward a public interest view. It argued that such<br />

representati<strong>on</strong> provides transparency to the scheme by providing a ‘public window’<br />

<strong>on</strong> its operati<strong>on</strong>s that ensures the industry group will be acting in the broader public<br />

interest. 157<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong> stated that the creati<strong>on</strong> of its<br />

independent Code Authority brings greater transparency and accountability to<br />

complaints handling. 158 Similarly, Financial <strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Service commented<br />

that the scheme should be an entirely separate entity from the industry so there is no<br />

percepti<strong>on</strong> of bias. 159<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that good administrati<strong>on</strong> of a scheme underpins good<br />

practice. It can identify issues, collect data, m<strong>on</strong>itor the scheme, ensure compliance<br />

costs are at an effective minimum level and enhance credibility and accountability.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders the type of administrati<strong>on</strong> (i.e. whether a scheme can be<br />

administered by individual firms, industry associati<strong>on</strong>s, or some form of<br />

independent body) will depend <strong>on</strong> the nature of the specific problem and the nature<br />

of the industry.<br />

Data collecti<strong>on</strong><br />

Data collecti<strong>on</strong> by an industry scheme is important as a valuable source of market<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> about the origins and causes of complaints. It also enables identificati<strong>on</strong><br />

of systemic problems which need to be addressed by industry members. This, in<br />

turn, can improve market outcomes for c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

ASIC stated that a vital role that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can play in the broader regulatory<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment is to identify emerging industry risk areas. In doing so self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

can serve to alert industry to potential problems before they actually materialise in<br />

market misc<strong>on</strong>duct. 160<br />

156 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 14, p. 3.<br />

157 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 42, p. 26.<br />

158 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 36, p. 11.<br />

159 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 15, p. 4.<br />

160 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 18.<br />

65


The C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre of Victoria, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit Legal Service (Vic) and the<br />

Financial and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Rights Council (Vic) comment that systemic issues arise out<br />

of comm<strong>on</strong> practices by industry and/or experiences of multiple c<strong>on</strong>sumers. The<br />

identificati<strong>on</strong> of such issues provides valuable informati<strong>on</strong> to industry as to the<br />

effects of its processes <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumers as well as allowing soluti<strong>on</strong>s to be found. 161<br />

Generally, systemic problems can be identified two ways. First, an individual<br />

complaint may be such as to identify a system or process problem which has the<br />

potential to affect many c<strong>on</strong>sumers. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, the accumulati<strong>on</strong> of complaints and<br />

further statistical analysis will either identify or suggest the existence of a systemic<br />

problem.<br />

For example, the Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman commented that its<br />

primary role in this c<strong>on</strong>text is notifying individual members, referring the issue to<br />

relevant regulators (e.g. the <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s Authority or ACCC), or<br />

highlighting the issues in public forums and in the media. 162<br />

As discussed by the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre of Victoria, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit Legal<br />

Service (Vic) and the Financial and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Rights Council (Vic), it is inherently<br />

difficult for industries to step back from their business to identify systemic problems,<br />

particularly where the process or practice is accepted within the industry. Further,<br />

the cost of implementing strategies to address such issues may be perceived to be<br />

c<strong>on</strong>trary to a profit-making imperative. 163<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that data collecti<strong>on</strong> is a valuable tool in identifying systemic<br />

issues which need to be addressed by industry members which, in turn, can improve<br />

market outcomes for c<strong>on</strong>sumers. Also, depending <strong>on</strong> the nature of the specific<br />

problem being addressed, dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes can offer industry an effective<br />

means to identify systemic issues.<br />

Transparency<br />

Transparency is another desirable feature of schemes. As c<strong>on</strong>sumers cannot guard<br />

against specific industry problems that they do not know exist, transparency in<br />

schemes is an important mechanism to ensure credibility and accountability.<br />

A number of organisati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>sulted discussed the importance of transparency in<br />

enhancing the credibility of schemes. For example, the <strong>Australian</strong> Toy Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

suggested that any self-regulatory arrangements should be transparent and its<br />

operati<strong>on</strong> open to scrutiny, and subject to a process of review after a set period<br />

(approximately 3-5 years). 164<br />

161 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 29, p. 13.<br />

162 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 21, p. 12.<br />

163 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 29, p. 13.<br />

164 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 23, p. 3.<br />

66


The Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Advisory Council commented that <strong>on</strong>e thing<br />

that seems to be c<strong>on</strong>sistent am<strong>on</strong>gst all codes is that c<strong>on</strong>sumers are not informed of<br />

who’s complying and who’s not. This informati<strong>on</strong> is clearly potentially important to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers when choosing which company they may do business with. 165<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that schemes ought to be transparent and open to scrutiny to<br />

improve market outcomes for c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

Dispute procedures and sancti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> adherence to schemes<br />

For self-regulatory schemes to achieve their objectives, compliance by industry<br />

members is a key feature. Compliance by industry ensures that specific industry<br />

problems are being addressed. As noted previously, some self-regulatory schemes<br />

are voluntary in their nature whereas others are mandatory. The degree of<br />

compliance can depend <strong>on</strong> a number of factors, such as whether firms obtain<br />

marketing benefits from it, whether they are in a competitive market, or whether<br />

they risk sancti<strong>on</strong>s for n<strong>on</strong>-compliance.<br />

In house compliance<br />

One means of compliance with self-regulatory schemes is through internal<br />

mechanisms.<br />

In relati<strong>on</strong> to codes, the ACCC commented that the code’s administrati<strong>on</strong> body needs<br />

to ensure that each participant has some form of in house compliance system to<br />

ensure compliance with the code. It can also assist compliance at this level with<br />

advice and training. It noted that, in Australia, code compliance manuals are being<br />

developed for code schemes. These manuals are based <strong>on</strong> the recently released<br />

standard <strong>on</strong> compliance programs (AS3806). 166<br />

Similarly, ASIC commented that adequate training of staff is good practice , in other<br />

words compliance officers in individual firms, staff in scheme administrators and,<br />

where appropriate, staff in external complaints resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes. 167<br />

NRMA also c<strong>on</strong>sidered that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is enhanced by establishing a specialised<br />

unit within the company to deal with compliance. This helps to ensure that all<br />

customer c<strong>on</strong>cerns and issues are given a high priority, are managed by the<br />

appropriate business unit and are addressed in a c<strong>on</strong>sistent and timely manner. 168<br />

165 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 14, p. 3.<br />

166 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 42, p. 26.<br />

167 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 15.<br />

168 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 7, p. 3.<br />

67


Similarly, the AAMI customer charter sets out some clearly defined rights for its<br />

customers.<br />

A competitive market can be another driver of compliance. For example, the<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> Food and Grocery Council commented that industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is<br />

most effective addressing issues where individual companies can play an active role<br />

in promoting voluntary codes, m<strong>on</strong>itoring compliance in the market place, and<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tributing to code enforcement through a complaint resoluti<strong>on</strong> process. 169<br />

Similarly, ADMA c<strong>on</strong>sidered that its direct marketing code brings peer pressure to<br />

bear <strong>on</strong> members who breach the code, a powerful coercive force in the marketplace.<br />

As such, member compliance is driven by enlightened self-interest, not fear of state<br />

interventi<strong>on</strong> in business affairs. 170<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that compliance with standards across the industry is<br />

necessary for good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. It ensures that specific industry<br />

problems are being addressed and the benefits from standards of practice in schemes<br />

are flowing to c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

Complaint handling<br />

Depending <strong>on</strong> the nature of the specific problem, self-regulati<strong>on</strong> should incorporate<br />

complaint handling and dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms to provide appropriate<br />

redress to customers where the standard of c<strong>on</strong>duct was breached. Redress<br />

encourages industry members to react promptly and fairly to complaints by having<br />

internal complaint resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms and, where appropriate, subscribing to<br />

some form of fair and independent dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme.<br />

These processes are essential to ensure that dissatisfied c<strong>on</strong>sumers have access to<br />

cost-effective mechanisms for resolving their complaints about the c<strong>on</strong>duct of<br />

members of the code. The formal legal system involving court litigati<strong>on</strong> is not<br />

designed to provide quick and cheap complaints resoluti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

For example, the Instituti<strong>on</strong> of Engineers commented that the most secure protecti<strong>on</strong><br />

for the community lies in the fundamental requirement of its code that registered<br />

pers<strong>on</strong>s must practice within the limits of their pers<strong>on</strong>al and professi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

competence, and in the assurance that they will be subject to effective disciplinary<br />

acti<strong>on</strong> if they fail to observe that c<strong>on</strong>straint. As such, the Instituti<strong>on</strong> has procedures<br />

for dealing with complaints about members including investigati<strong>on</strong> of the complaint<br />

and applying sancti<strong>on</strong>s where appropriate. 171<br />

ASIC stated that accessible and effective complaint resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms serve to<br />

buttress c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence. They can also provide benefits to business, for<br />

169 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 30, p. 13.<br />

170 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 36, p. 11.<br />

171 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 26, p. 15.<br />

68


example, by enabling industry to identify and address systemic c<strong>on</strong>sumer problems,<br />

thereby maintaining c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence and avoiding the need for Government<br />

interventi<strong>on</strong>. 172<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that businesses should establish fair and effective internal<br />

procedures to address and resp<strong>on</strong>d to c<strong>on</strong>sumer complaints and difficulties:<br />

(a) within a reas<strong>on</strong>able time;<br />

(b) in a reas<strong>on</strong>able manner;<br />

(c) free of charge to the customer; and<br />

(d) without prejudicing the rights of the c<strong>on</strong>sumer to seek legal redress.<br />

If a c<strong>on</strong>sumer is unsatisfied with the resoluti<strong>on</strong> process provided by the internal<br />

complaint handling mechanism, then it is good practice for the business to provide<br />

the c<strong>on</strong>sumer with informati<strong>on</strong> regarding any external dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> body to<br />

which it subscribes or any relevant Government body, such as a Fair Trading<br />

Agency.<br />

NSW Legal Aid argued that any self-regulatory scheme must allow for the<br />

establishment of internal dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> procedures and for the m<strong>on</strong>itoring and<br />

improvement of such processes. 173<br />

The NRMA stated that an element of good practice has been to standardise the<br />

process of dealing with customer c<strong>on</strong>cerns. For example, NRMA adopts a three step<br />

process of, first, referring the issue to the relevant business area, sec<strong>on</strong>d, allowing the<br />

Customer Relati<strong>on</strong>s area to mediate and, third, taking the matter to the independent<br />

dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> body. 174<br />

At the more interventi<strong>on</strong>ist end of the self-regulatory spectrum where businesses<br />

may be dealing with a large amount of complaints and/or dealing with complaints<br />

of a more serious nature, an external dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme may be appropriate.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that a business should provide clear and accessible<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>sumers <strong>on</strong> any independent customer dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

mechanism to which the business subscribes.<br />

Such independent customer dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms should be: 175<br />

172 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 16.<br />

173 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 24, p. 4.<br />

174 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 7, pp. 3, 4.<br />

175 For more informati<strong>on</strong> regarding external dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes, businesses are<br />

encouraged to c<strong>on</strong>sult the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth’s Benchmarks for <strong>Industry</strong>-based Customer Dispute<br />

Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Schemes, 1997. This publicati<strong>on</strong> can be accessed through the Treasury web-site:<br />

www.treasury.gov.au/publicati<strong>on</strong>s. There are also a number of resources available in relati<strong>on</strong><br />

69


(a) accessible;<br />

(b) independent;<br />

(c) fair;<br />

(d) accountable;<br />

(e) efficient; and<br />

(f) effective.<br />

As discussed in chapter 8, a number of industries have an external dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

scheme.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer representatives <strong>on</strong> dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes can also ensure credibility<br />

and independence. A number of organisati<strong>on</strong>s including industry, c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups<br />

and Government all commented <strong>on</strong> the usefulness of c<strong>on</strong>sumer representatives <strong>on</strong><br />

schemes. For example, the ACCC commented that, where appropriate,<br />

industry-based code schemes aimed at delivering fair trading outcomes need to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tain appropriate c<strong>on</strong>sumer/user representati<strong>on</strong> in complaints handling. It argued<br />

that such representati<strong>on</strong> provides transparency to the scheme by providing a ‘public<br />

window’ <strong>on</strong> its operati<strong>on</strong>s that ensures the industry group will be acting in the<br />

broader public interest. 176<br />

Similarly, the Law Council of Australia argued that as effective enforcement is the<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly way to protect c<strong>on</strong>sumers’ rights, a minimum c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> for successful<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the provisi<strong>on</strong> of industry funded independent c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

representatives, so that the various uneven elements of the c<strong>on</strong>sumers/producer<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship can be remedied. 177<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that self-regulatory schemes should aim to provide<br />

appropriate redress to c<strong>on</strong>sumers where the standard of c<strong>on</strong>duct has been breached.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer redress is essential to ensure that dissatisfied c<strong>on</strong>sumers have access to<br />

cost-effective mechanisms for resolving their complaints about the c<strong>on</strong>duct of<br />

members of schemes. The appropriate redress mechanism will depend <strong>on</strong> the nature<br />

of the specific problem trying to be addressed.<br />

Sancti<strong>on</strong>s for n<strong>on</strong>-compliance<br />

It will generally be desirable for the self-regulatory scheme to provide for a range of<br />

enforcement opti<strong>on</strong>s, depending <strong>on</strong> the nature of the breach. For example, immediate<br />

expulsi<strong>on</strong> may not be a suitable sancti<strong>on</strong> for a minor breach of the scheme. However,<br />

to internal complaint handling, including AS4269, the <strong>Australian</strong> Standard <strong>on</strong> complaint<br />

handling. The Standard is produced by the private organisati<strong>on</strong>, Standards Australia.<br />

176 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 42, p. 26.<br />

177 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 19, p. 11.<br />

70


effective sancti<strong>on</strong>s can raise the level of credibility and c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence in<br />

schemes. A comment often heard during the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s was that<br />

schemes need to have ‘teeth’.<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> associati<strong>on</strong>s use a range of different sancti<strong>on</strong>s. For example, the Instituti<strong>on</strong><br />

of Engineers commented that all of their members are bound by their Code of Ethics.<br />

They then have procedures for dealing with complaints about members and are able<br />

to apply a range of sancti<strong>on</strong>s including expulsi<strong>on</strong> and suspensi<strong>on</strong> of membership. 178<br />

Similarly, the <strong>Australian</strong> Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Associati<strong>on</strong> Code of Practice<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tains a hierarchy of sancti<strong>on</strong>s ranging from corrective advertising, fines of up to<br />

$30 000, or expulsi<strong>on</strong>. 179<br />

The Department of <strong>Industry</strong>, Science and Resources argued that with voluntary<br />

participati<strong>on</strong>, effective sancti<strong>on</strong>s and incentives can be applied, with low scope for<br />

the benefits being shared with n<strong>on</strong>-participants. It submitted that voluntary<br />

participati<strong>on</strong> ⎯ backed by str<strong>on</strong>g incentives to participate ⎯ appears to provide a<br />

str<strong>on</strong>ger framework and higher degree of success, independent of the size of the<br />

industry associati<strong>on</strong>. 180<br />

On the other hand, the Motor Trades Associati<strong>on</strong> of Australia commented that<br />

sancti<strong>on</strong>s, if they exist, are usually not effective because of the voluntary nature of<br />

the regulatory scheme. For example, if a sancti<strong>on</strong> is to be imposed for<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-compliance, the offending party can simply ‘opt out’ of the regulatory scheme<br />

and c<strong>on</strong>tinue with the behaviour. 181<br />

ASIC argued that the c<strong>on</strong>sequences of inadequate enforcement in an industry such as<br />

the financial services industry can be serious. The industry is heavily dependent <strong>on</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence — if c<strong>on</strong>sumers suffer financial losses due, for example to<br />

intermediary misc<strong>on</strong>duct in c<strong>on</strong>traventi<strong>on</strong> of the requirements of a self-regulatory<br />

scheme, the reputati<strong>on</strong> of the <strong>Australian</strong> financial markets may suffer. Accordingly,<br />

ASIC c<strong>on</strong>sidered that it is essential that self-regulatory schemes be underpinned by<br />

effective sancti<strong>on</strong>s. 182<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong> recommended a ‘toolkit’ of acti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

underpinned with Government involvement. These include:<br />

¾ rewriting of misleading, incorrect or false c<strong>on</strong>sumer informati<strong>on</strong>;<br />

¾ corrective advertising; and<br />

¾ retraining staff. 183<br />

178 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 26, p. 15.<br />

179 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 10, p. 3.<br />

180 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 31, p. 22.<br />

181 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 1, p. 1.<br />

182 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 15.<br />

183 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 16, p. 2.<br />

71


The Department of <strong>Industry</strong>, Science and Resources also noted that the use of<br />

penalties and/or sancti<strong>on</strong>s within self-regulatory regimes require careful<br />

c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> as they can lead to retaliatory acti<strong>on</strong> by participants. 184 Similarly, the<br />

Motor Trades Associati<strong>on</strong> of Australia noted that if sancti<strong>on</strong>s are pursued by the<br />

self-regulatory scheme administrators, perhaps a peer group or industry associati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

then there is a questi<strong>on</strong> about protecting the administrators from legal acti<strong>on</strong> by the<br />

party affected by the sancti<strong>on</strong>. 185<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that there should be a range of sancti<strong>on</strong>s that can be used by<br />

industry in order to achieve compliance depending <strong>on</strong> the nature of the problem and<br />

the c<strong>on</strong>sequences of n<strong>on</strong>-compliance. Sancti<strong>on</strong>s can raise the level of c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

c<strong>on</strong>fidence in schemes. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that the severity of the sancti<strong>on</strong><br />

should also depend <strong>on</strong> the seriousness of the breach.<br />

Competitive implicati<strong>on</strong>s and the authorisati<strong>on</strong> process<br />

Where industry has the commitment to collectively sancti<strong>on</strong> breaches of a<br />

self-regulatory scheme there is the possibility that such acti<strong>on</strong> may amount to<br />

anti-competitive behaviour. In most cases such acti<strong>on</strong> may not amount to<br />

anti-competitive behaviour or the benefit to the public may outweigh such<br />

behaviour. However, to avoid any threat of legal acti<strong>on</strong> for breach of the competiti<strong>on</strong><br />

provisi<strong>on</strong>s of the Trade Practices Act 1974, a procedure exists whereby industry can<br />

have the arrangement authorised.<br />

Prior authorisati<strong>on</strong> for such a collective arrangement can be sought from the ACCC<br />

which assesses whether there is sufficient public benefit flowing from the<br />

arrangement to outweigh any anti-competitive effects. An authorisati<strong>on</strong> from the<br />

ACCC gives parties involved in the anti-competitive arrangement immunity from<br />

court acti<strong>on</strong> taken under the competiti<strong>on</strong> provisi<strong>on</strong>s of the Trade Practices Act 1974.<br />

The authorisati<strong>on</strong> process can be time c<strong>on</strong>suming and expensive, but it does provide<br />

industry with protecti<strong>on</strong> against legal acti<strong>on</strong>. Hence, if industry believes that there is<br />

a significant risk that their scheme has anti-competitive elements then authorisati<strong>on</strong><br />

may be a prudent course of acti<strong>on</strong> to pursue. 186 It is generally up to industry to<br />

manage this risk and ensure any self-regulatory scheme encourages competiti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

184 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 31, p. 22.<br />

185 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 1, p. 1.<br />

186 See Part VII — Trade Practices Act 1974. Aspects of a code which might require the code to be<br />

authorised include restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> membership, prohibiti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> code members dealing with<br />

other industry participants, and imposing sancti<strong>on</strong>s for n<strong>on</strong>-compliance where such sancti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

effect a party’s ability to compete. Most applicati<strong>on</strong>s attract a fee of $15000. Details of the ACCC<br />

authorisati<strong>on</strong> process are available from the ACCC website at:<br />

http://www.accc.gov.au/adjudicati<strong>on</strong>/fs-adjudicate.htm.<br />

72


For example, the <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong> stated that punitive<br />

acti<strong>on</strong>s against members, which may otherwise be judged anti-competitive have been<br />

authorised by the ACCC. 187<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that industry needs to manage the risk of any<br />

anti-competitive practices in schemes, particularly where sancti<strong>on</strong>s are involved.<br />

Although the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that there needs to be a public benefit justificati<strong>on</strong><br />

process, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> notes that there has been some criticisms of the authorisati<strong>on</strong><br />

process. 188<br />

M<strong>on</strong>itoring and reviewing<br />

M<strong>on</strong>itoring<br />

As discussed elsewhere, m<strong>on</strong>itoring is an important aspect of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to<br />

ensure that agreed standards are being met. Establishing a self-regulatory scheme is<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly part of the equati<strong>on</strong>. <strong>Industry</strong> also needs to be aware that it has a c<strong>on</strong>tinual<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>sibility to ensure that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is addressing its objectives and ethical<br />

members are not being disadvantaged.<br />

ASIC commented that the compliance m<strong>on</strong>itoring mechanisms should be tailored to<br />

the particular scheme’s circumstances. The appropriate compliance m<strong>on</strong>itoring<br />

mechanisms will depend <strong>on</strong> the identified regulatory outcomes and the nature of the<br />

particular industry sector. There are various methods for m<strong>on</strong>itoring compliance,<br />

including:<br />

¾ the internal c<strong>on</strong>trols of the individual firm;<br />

¾ annual reporting <strong>on</strong> compliance;<br />

¾ independent m<strong>on</strong>itoring;<br />

¾ an external compliance audit; or<br />

¾ the regulator. 189<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Chamber of Commerce and <strong>Industry</strong> stated that encouraging<br />

managers and employees to take resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for their own acti<strong>on</strong>s is its preferred<br />

approach. 190<br />

187 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 36, p. 11.<br />

188 Chapter 7 — approaches to promoting and coordinating industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, discusses the<br />

authorisati<strong>on</strong> process further.<br />

189 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, pp. 15, 16.<br />

190 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 27, p. 5.<br />

73


However, some organisati<strong>on</strong>s have argued that the Government needs to m<strong>on</strong>itor<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> more closely. For example, the Royal Aer<strong>on</strong>autical Society argued that<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> must always be accompanied by a rigorous system of dialogue with,<br />

and policing by, the Government agency resp<strong>on</strong>sible for the safety of the public. 191<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders m<strong>on</strong>itoring is crucial to good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

M<strong>on</strong>itoring ensures that the scheme is addressing specific problems within an<br />

industry. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that the role of Government in m<strong>on</strong>itoring will<br />

depend <strong>on</strong> the circumstances. As a general principle, if there is a public policy<br />

objective to do so (e.g. health and safety reas<strong>on</strong>s), then the Government may choose<br />

to be directly involved in the m<strong>on</strong>itoring of schemes. 192<br />

Accountability<br />

The self-regulatory scheme should publicly report whether its standards are being<br />

met. This can improve credibility and c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence in schemes.<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Toy Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that any self-regulatory arrangement<br />

needs to be accountable in terms of the body administering the scheme. 193<br />

The ACCC commented that annual reports <strong>on</strong> the operati<strong>on</strong> of the code should be<br />

produced by the code administrati<strong>on</strong> committee, allowing for periodic assessment of<br />

the scheme’s effectiveness. 194<br />

For example, the <strong>Australian</strong> Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Associati<strong>on</strong> stated that<br />

breaches of the code are reported in their annual reports. 195 Similarly, the <strong>Australian</strong><br />

Supermarket Institute stated that public reporting occurs annually <strong>on</strong> the Scanning<br />

Code’s operati<strong>on</strong>. 196<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that accountability is an element of good practice in<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that annual reports are a useful tool to<br />

allow a periodic assessment of the scheme’s effectiveness.<br />

Review<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that periodic reviews of standards should also be<br />

undertaken to ensure that they are being met and are relevant and up-to-date. This<br />

ensures that the scheme is still appropriate to the specific problems it is seeking to<br />

address and allows for other stakeholders, such as c<strong>on</strong>sumers and Government, to be<br />

191 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 40, p. 4.<br />

192 Chapter 7 — approaches to promoting and coordinating industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, discusses the<br />

role of Government in this c<strong>on</strong>text further.<br />

193 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 23, p. 3.<br />

194 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 42, p. 27.<br />

195 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 10, p. 4.<br />

196 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 11, p. 2.<br />

74


involved. Preferably, reviews should be periodic, independent and be made publicly<br />

available.<br />

ASIC stated that self-regulatory schemes should be regularly reviewed for efficiency<br />

and effectiveness. Such reviews are essential to deal with market changes due to<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong> and other forces which can rapidly lead to out-of-date regulati<strong>on</strong>. It<br />

argued that reviews of individual schemes are usually best c<strong>on</strong>ducted by an<br />

independent c<strong>on</strong>sultant in c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the stakeholders involved in the<br />

development of the scheme (i.e. industry members, c<strong>on</strong>sumer organisati<strong>on</strong>s and the<br />

regulator). 197<br />

ASIC suggested that scheme reviews should be undertaken at least <strong>on</strong>ce every three<br />

years. This should encompass the c<strong>on</strong>tent of the code and the operati<strong>on</strong> of the<br />

external complaint resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme. It argued that it is also desirable that reviews<br />

are publicly c<strong>on</strong>ducted wherever possible. 198<br />

Insurance Enquiries and Complaints Limited commented that their code and scheme<br />

are reviewed periodically so that a flexible approach towards a changing market<br />

place is maintained. In particular, it commented that the scheme has evolved over<br />

time with the jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> being progressively widened. The company issues an<br />

annual review which reports <strong>on</strong> all aspects of the scheme, the code and now the<br />

privacy principles. 199<br />

Cost-effective practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

Throughout this report, reference has been made to the benefits of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

However, self-regulati<strong>on</strong> does come at a cost to both the industry and c<strong>on</strong>sumer. The<br />

costs involved in administering an inefficient self-regulatory scheme may be<br />

translated into higher prices for c<strong>on</strong>sumers resulting in a poor market outcome for<br />

both business and c<strong>on</strong>sumers. Compliance costs can also be high for business, which<br />

in turn, can be passed <strong>on</strong>to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. However, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> is not touting that<br />

schemes should be cost-effective at the risk of sacrificing c<strong>on</strong>sumer rights for<br />

example. It is necessary to ensure that the scheme is the effective minimum soluti<strong>on</strong><br />

for the specific problem in hand.<br />

Benefits of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> over explicit regulati<strong>on</strong> and courts system<br />

During the inquiry, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> received a lot of anecdotal evidence to suggest that<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is more cost-effective than government regulati<strong>on</strong> and the court<br />

system. 200 For example, A Guide to Regulati<strong>on</strong> (1998) commented that there are cost<br />

197 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 19.<br />

198 Ibid.<br />

199 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 8, p. 4.<br />

200 Chapter 5 indicates that if there are cost advantages and/or increased flexibility in using<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, then a scheme has a better chance of success.<br />

75


advantages from tailor-made soluti<strong>on</strong>s and less formal mechanisms such as access to<br />

quick complaints handling and redress mechanisms. However, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

recognises that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is not necessarily cheaper than government regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Furthermore, it is ultimately the c<strong>on</strong>sumer that bears the cost of any form of<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> in most cases.<br />

NRMA stated that compared with more direct Government regulati<strong>on</strong>, in many<br />

cases industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> results in lower regulatory costs. For example, for<br />

general insurance claims, handling costs can be reduced by producing policy<br />

documentati<strong>on</strong> in a standardised format. It also argued that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> will<br />

normally have faster and simpler dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> procedures, again resulting in<br />

lower regulatory costs. In competitive markets, these lower regulatory costs are<br />

generally passed <strong>on</strong>to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. 201<br />

The Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman also commented that its dispute<br />

scheme has provided a free and timely forum for the redress of c<strong>on</strong>sumer complaints<br />

in c<strong>on</strong>trast to costly and time c<strong>on</strong>suming acti<strong>on</strong> in courts or c<strong>on</strong>sumer tribunals. 202<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, the Office of Small Business stated that although small business often<br />

have legal recourse in disputes, their access to justice can be c<strong>on</strong>strained by the cost<br />

of going to court, the l<strong>on</strong>g time and delays before their case is heard, the disparity in<br />

the quality of representati<strong>on</strong> and their need to preserve business relati<strong>on</strong>ships. In<br />

many cases, neither party achieves a satisfactory result from a Court judgement. 203<br />

In most cases, the Office of Small Business argued that self-regulatory approaches<br />

can offer small business a low-cost, quick and flexible system for resolving disputes.<br />

It submitted that this provides a viable alternative to litigati<strong>on</strong>, typically achieving a<br />

success rate of around 80 per cent, without costly and time-c<strong>on</strong>suming legal acti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

For example, the Office of Small Business quoted that some studies show that using<br />

dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes can cost as little as five percent of the cost of going to<br />

court. 204<br />

201 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 7, p. 2.<br />

202 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 21, p. 9.<br />

203 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 38, p. 2.<br />

204 Ibid.<br />

76


Cost of schemes<br />

While a lot of the benefits and elements of good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> have been<br />

flagged, the schemes come at a cost. And depending <strong>on</strong> the specific problem being<br />

addressed, this cost can be significant.<br />

As stated by the Instituti<strong>on</strong> of Engineers Australia any form of regulati<strong>on</strong>, whether<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> or otherwise, requires an allocati<strong>on</strong> of resources and will necessarily<br />

involve compliance costs that may or may not become <strong>on</strong>erous. It argued that<br />

effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> requires not <strong>on</strong>ly standards or codes of practice, but also<br />

effective mechanisms for dealing with complaints of n<strong>on</strong>-compliance with those<br />

codes. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> requires extensive community and business educati<strong>on</strong>, and<br />

requires a commitment from all industry players to work effectively. 205<br />

Similarly, the Federati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Australian</strong> Radio Broadcasters noted that while some<br />

may see the overlay of an implementati<strong>on</strong> and m<strong>on</strong>itoring system as a level of<br />

bureaucracy, it is clear that there is an expectati<strong>on</strong> that industries and industry<br />

bodies take resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for the effective operati<strong>on</strong> of their systems of self or<br />

co-regulati<strong>on</strong>. If there is a cost in either time or m<strong>on</strong>ey then so be it — ‘self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

is not meant to be cost free regulati<strong>on</strong>’, according to <strong>on</strong>e observer. 206<br />

The cost of self-regulatory schemes can vary greatly. At <strong>on</strong>e end of the spectrum,<br />

industry initiatives that improve the amount of informati<strong>on</strong> available to c<strong>on</strong>sumers<br />

to make informed choices can be relatively inexpensive. For example, a guideline<br />

may <strong>on</strong>ly involve printing and staff time costs.<br />

Similarly, more sophisticated schemes can be fairly inexpensive depending <strong>on</strong> what<br />

is trying to be achieved. For example, the <strong>Australian</strong> Supermarket Institute stated<br />

that the cost of the Scanning Code administrati<strong>on</strong> includes materials, printing and<br />

distributi<strong>on</strong>, and staff time handling issues. It is estimated this cost would not exceed<br />

$40 000 per annum. 207<br />

Whereas, at the more interventi<strong>on</strong>ist end of the self-regulatory spectrum, schemes<br />

can cost more. For example, the Federati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Australian</strong> Commercial Televisi<strong>on</strong><br />

Stati<strong>on</strong>s estimated that the cost of its scheme to the industry is at least $3 milli<strong>on</strong><br />

annually. It commented that the industry’s Code of Practice places c<strong>on</strong>siderable<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>sibility <strong>on</strong> individual stati<strong>on</strong>s, and is relatively resource-intensive and costly<br />

to operate. However, it believed the industry supports the process because it is more<br />

efficient, simple and direct than any regulatory alternative. 208<br />

Further, the bigger dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes that resolve customer disputes are<br />

expensive to run. For example, the <strong>Australian</strong> Banking <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman,<br />

205 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 26, p. 23.<br />

206 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 35, p. 10.<br />

207 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 11, p. 4.<br />

208 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 34, p. 9.<br />

77


Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman and General Insurance Enquiries and<br />

Complaints schemes all cost in excess of $3 milli<strong>on</strong> per year. 209<br />

Compliance costs<br />

However, the administrative costs of self-regulatory schemes is <strong>on</strong>ly part of the story.<br />

Compliance costs are also associated with self-regulatory schemes. It is necessary to<br />

ensure that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> does not itself become a burden to industry with <strong>on</strong>erous<br />

compliance costs, particularly for small businesses.<br />

Again, there is a spectrum of compliance costs for business. At the lower end of the<br />

spectrum, schemes that raise the level of informati<strong>on</strong> may simply involve preparing a<br />

disclosure document for example. Similarly, in complying with standards, there are<br />

low compliance costs involved in following the standard <strong>on</strong> work safety boots.<br />

Whereas, the quality management system standard (ISO9000) produced by<br />

Standards Australia is more expensive to implement depending <strong>on</strong> the size of the<br />

company. 210<br />

At the more interventi<strong>on</strong>ist end of the spectrum, codes and dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

schemes can be expensive for businesses to comply with. The Financial <strong>Industry</strong><br />

Complaints Service stated that various levels of funding are required depending <strong>on</strong><br />

the number of disputes and the quality and expertise of staff. Generally, the costs are<br />

allocated to members by a capacity to pay , in other words the wealthier members<br />

pay the most. 211<br />

For example, Insurance Enquiries and Complaints Limited stated that its scheme is<br />

funded by a combinati<strong>on</strong> of a levy up<strong>on</strong> insurers and fee per case charges to insurers.<br />

Approximately 60 per cent of its budget is met by a levy up<strong>on</strong> the pers<strong>on</strong>al lines<br />

premium income of member companies. Companies either pay the minimum levy of<br />

$1 600 or a levy based <strong>on</strong> their proporti<strong>on</strong> of pers<strong>on</strong>al lines premium income. The<br />

other 40 per cent of the budget is met by a fee per case payment. 212<br />

In comparis<strong>on</strong>, the Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman scheme commented<br />

that its funding mechanism is based <strong>on</strong> two principles. First, that each member pays<br />

for the scheme’s complaint handling services based <strong>on</strong> the number, and relative<br />

percentage of total complaints, raised by the scheme against that member. Sec<strong>on</strong>d,<br />

the complaint handling fees are structured in a way as to provide a financial<br />

incentive for members to resolve complaints in a timely manner. The handling fees<br />

are $15 for an initial enquiry, up to $1 130 for dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>. 213 As a corollary, a<br />

member has no financial obligati<strong>on</strong> to the Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong><br />

209 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s with industry dispute schemes, November 1999.<br />

210 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with Standards Australia, Sydney, 29 November 1999.<br />

211 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 15, p. 4.<br />

212 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 8, p. 4.<br />

213 Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman, Annual <strong>Report</strong> 1998-99, p.10.<br />

78


Ombudsman if no complaints are made against that member. There are no<br />

membership or joining fees associated with the scheme. 214<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that as businesses become more aware and familiar with a<br />

self-regulatory scheme then compliance costs can be reduced. Indeed, often during<br />

the self-regulatory scheme’s first year of operati<strong>on</strong> compliance costs are particularly<br />

high as businesses are training staff etc, but in the following years costs are usually<br />

reduced. However, compliance costs can also increase later down the track.<br />

For example, the Service Providers <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> argued that the<br />

self-regulatory participati<strong>on</strong> burden is likely to increase, rather than decrease in the<br />

telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s. It c<strong>on</strong>sidered the increasing complexity of inter-working as the<br />

wholesale market and new applicati<strong>on</strong>s develop will drive this trend, leading to calls<br />

for more and more codes and standards, as well as the need to revisit and overhaul<br />

existing codes. The accelerating take-up of e-commerce and e-business will also lead<br />

to more demands for codes and standards to meet c<strong>on</strong>sumer expectati<strong>on</strong>s and<br />

industry inter-working requirements. 215<br />

The Service Providers <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> argued that as more regulatory and<br />

industry bodies engage in the process of writing standards, codes and guidelines,<br />

compliance becomes an increasing burden <strong>on</strong> organisati<strong>on</strong>s. It commented that not<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly is it difficult or impossible for most organisati<strong>on</strong>s to participate in the creati<strong>on</strong><br />

of these instruments, it becomes very difficult to be fully aware of the range of<br />

regulatory instruments that apply to an individual organisati<strong>on</strong> and its business<br />

operati<strong>on</strong>s. When this situati<strong>on</strong> is reached, it introduces major challenges for staff<br />

trainers and compliance managers. 216<br />

Cost to smaller industry associati<strong>on</strong>s and businesses<br />

A self-regulatory scheme stands a greater chance of success if it is backed by a large<br />

and well structured industry associati<strong>on</strong>. Primarily, this assists in regards to the costs<br />

associated with establishing and maintaining regimes, ensuring broad participati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

and issues of enforcement, including sancti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Where no large industry associati<strong>on</strong> exists, costs would appear to be a prohibiting<br />

factor in developing and administering a regime. As discussed by the Department of<br />

<strong>Industry</strong>, Science and Resources, in such instances, sharing of the costs between<br />

participants and beneficiaries should be c<strong>on</strong>sidered <strong>on</strong> a cost recovery basis. It<br />

argued that such cost recovery principles would be regime specific but should<br />

encompass a clear process in determining who should pay for developing and<br />

214 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 21, p. 10.<br />

215 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 25, p. 4.<br />

216 Ibid.<br />

79


administering the regime and how charges should be structured ⎯ preferably based<br />

<strong>on</strong> tangible outcomes. 217<br />

Similarly, the Office of Small Business argued that it is generally accepted that small<br />

business is less able than big business to cope with the costs of participating in a<br />

scheme such as a code of c<strong>on</strong>duct, particularly when such a scheme is funded by<br />

industry levies. It argued that while big business is usually able to absorb such costs,<br />

small businesses in many cases have no opti<strong>on</strong> but to pass <strong>on</strong> these costs to the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer in the form of higher prices for goods and services. This can place small<br />

business at a competitive disadvantage to their larger counterparts. 218<br />

The Office of Small Business also argued that the methodology for the administrati<strong>on</strong><br />

of fees should be clearly established before any self-regulatory scheme is initiated. It<br />

suggested that the methodology should be as transparent as possible <strong>on</strong>ce in place.<br />

Small business is not likely to feel any ownership of the process of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> if<br />

the funding process is not accessible to them. Transparency also ensures that charges<br />

for administering a scheme have a direct relati<strong>on</strong>ship to actual administrati<strong>on</strong> costs,<br />

and that charges are regularly reviewed to maintain this relati<strong>on</strong>ship. 219<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that any funding arrangement for self-regulati<strong>on</strong> should be<br />

transparent and designed so as not to put businesses at a competitive disadvantage.<br />

217 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 31, p. 22.<br />

218 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 38, p. 3.<br />

219 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 38, p. 4.<br />

80


Minimum standards<br />

As discussed previously, the noti<strong>on</strong> of the effective minimum soluti<strong>on</strong> should apply<br />

to self-regulatory schemes.<br />

For example, the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Insurance Brokers Associati<strong>on</strong> does not support the<br />

impositi<strong>on</strong> of best practice standards as they are not always appropriate. In many<br />

cases the standards set are in fact best practice. However, this is <strong>on</strong>ly where it is<br />

appropriate. It argued that where this is not the case, minimum standards apply that<br />

provide proper protecti<strong>on</strong> for c<strong>on</strong>sumers. 220<br />

The Nati<strong>on</strong>al Insurance Brokers Associati<strong>on</strong> also noted that depending <strong>on</strong> the<br />

resources or corporate culture of the relevant entity, they choose whether to exceed<br />

these minimum standards. Certain entities may not be able to meet the compliance<br />

costs of best practice even though minimum standards will provide c<strong>on</strong>sumers with<br />

appropriate service and protecti<strong>on</strong>. 221<br />

Similarly, Clayt<strong>on</strong> Utz argued that codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct should be designed and drafted<br />

with an appropriate minimum standard in mind. Such a standard must be<br />

realistically set to ensure that it can realistically be complied with by industry<br />

participants. 222<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that standards in self-regulatory schemes should be the<br />

effective minimum soluti<strong>on</strong> to the specific problem.<br />

Summary<br />

The appropriate form of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> will depend <strong>on</strong> what is trying to be achieved<br />

which will vary depending <strong>on</strong> the industry. Good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> involves<br />

improving market outcomes for c<strong>on</strong>sumers at the lowest cost to businesses.<br />

220 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 3, p. 6.<br />

221 Ibid.<br />

222 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 43, p. 4.<br />

81


Chapter 7<br />

Approaches to promoting and<br />

coordinating industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> is to inquire and report into approaches to promoting and coordinating<br />

industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, including the appropriate role of Government and the<br />

development of industry codes as well as other approaches to self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The key players in the promoti<strong>on</strong> of industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> have always been<br />

industry, government and c<strong>on</strong>sumer advocates. The purpose of this chapter is to<br />

examine the respective roles of each group in the establishment of particular<br />

schemes.<br />

The roles of industry, government and c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups are dynamic, adapting to<br />

the changing face of the <strong>Australian</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy and, in particular, resp<strong>on</strong>ding to<br />

competitive pressures, regulatory reform, new technologies and the increasing<br />

globalisati<strong>on</strong> of c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets.<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> has shown a growing enthusiasm for initiating self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to engender<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence in new products and new technologies. Government has<br />

increasingly promoted self-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>s as part of its broader commitment to<br />

regulatory reform. C<strong>on</strong>sumer groups have embraced self-regulatory schemes to<br />

address c<strong>on</strong>sumer problems that cross jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>al boundaries. It is also worth<br />

noting the growth of third party certificati<strong>on</strong> schemes, particularly in the <strong>on</strong>line<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment, hinting at the commercial imperatives driving businesses to subscribe<br />

to some form of voluntary industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to win c<strong>on</strong>sumer trust.<br />

There is a variety of opti<strong>on</strong>s for designing and promoting self-regulatory schemes<br />

and what works for <strong>on</strong>e industry may not work for another. It follows that the ‘mix’<br />

of industry/government and c<strong>on</strong>sumer involvement that works well for <strong>on</strong>e<br />

self-regulatory scheme may be inappropriate for another.<br />

This chapter first examines the role that industry has played in promoting and<br />

coordinating self-regulatory schemes. This chapter then discusses the role of<br />

Government as a stakeholder, developer, promoter, m<strong>on</strong>itor and enforcer of<br />

schemes, as well as the crucial role that c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups have played and will<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tinue to play in the development of industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. Finally, the chapter<br />

analyses a number of opti<strong>on</strong>s to better co-ordinate and promote self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

including discussi<strong>on</strong> of whether a centralised Government agency, an oversight<br />

committee, or model codes would be appropriate.


C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> approaches to promoting self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

31. Experience has shown that industry will initiate a self-regulatory scheme in<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>se to a clear commercial imperative to win c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence and boost<br />

sales.<br />

32. <strong>Industry</strong> may promote self-regulati<strong>on</strong> as an alternative to government<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> where there is perceived to be a serious market failure or important<br />

social policy objective.<br />

Role of government in promoting and coordinating self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

33. Government involvement in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is justified when there is a public<br />

policy objective that would otherwise call for a regulatory resp<strong>on</strong>se.<br />

34. Government can assist in analysing systemic problems in an industry and in<br />

facilitating the design of a self-regulatory resp<strong>on</strong>se to address those systemic<br />

problems.<br />

35. The degree of government involvement will depend <strong>on</strong> the significance of<br />

the market failure or social policy objective being addressed and the c<strong>on</strong>sequences<br />

of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> proving ineffective.<br />

36. Government can assist in integrating schemes into the regulatory<br />

framework.<br />

37. Government is uniquely placed to promote internati<strong>on</strong>al cooperati<strong>on</strong> and<br />

harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of self-regulatory initiatives.<br />

Role of c<strong>on</strong>sumer advocates in promoting self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

38. C<strong>on</strong>sumer input is important in the development and in maintaining the<br />

relevance of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>sumer advocates can promote c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

c<strong>on</strong>fidence in self-regulatory schemes.<br />

39. C<strong>on</strong>sumer participati<strong>on</strong> is limited by human and financial resource<br />

c<strong>on</strong>straints if there is no financial assistance forthcoming from industry.<br />

Other c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

40. Code administrati<strong>on</strong> authorities established by industry should take<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for the m<strong>on</strong>itoring and review of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, in c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong><br />

with government and c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups.<br />

84


Role of industry<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> has initiated a host of self-regulatory schemes for a variety of reas<strong>on</strong>s. 223 For<br />

commercial reas<strong>on</strong>s, industry may develop a scheme to win c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence<br />

and boost sales. <strong>Industry</strong> may also promote self-regulati<strong>on</strong> as an alternative to<br />

government regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The promoti<strong>on</strong> of self-regulatory schemes is beneficial as a marketing tool to<br />

differentiate participants from competitors.<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can also build c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence when introducing new<br />

technology to the market. The <strong>Australian</strong> Code of Practice for Computerised Checkout<br />

Systems in Supermarkets was introduced to ease the transiti<strong>on</strong> away from individual<br />

item pricing to barcodes, including the provisi<strong>on</strong> of free items when the scanned<br />

price is higher than the shelf price. 224<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Chamber of Commerce and <strong>Industry</strong> commented that under<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, industry (often through associati<strong>on</strong>s) can assume resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for<br />

c<strong>on</strong>cerns raised by the community and is able to interact directly with stakeholders<br />

to resolve the problem. It suggested that industry associati<strong>on</strong>s can play a key role in<br />

delivering a coordinated approach to issues thus ensuring nati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>sistency. 225<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Supermarket Institute commented that the Code of Practice for the<br />

Fruit Juice <strong>Industry</strong> was developed by the <strong>Australian</strong> Citrus <strong>Industry</strong> Council to<br />

promote truth in labelling and fair trade of orange juice and other products. It has<br />

been designed to ensure that fruit juice is not adulterated and that the public is not<br />

otherwise misled about fruit juice products. The <strong>Australian</strong> Supermarket Institute<br />

commented that in taking this acti<strong>on</strong> itself, the fruit juice industry feels that it has<br />

enhanced both the image of the industry and the marketability of its fruit juice<br />

products. 226<br />

Similarly, the <strong>Australian</strong> Society of Certified Practising Accountants and the Institute<br />

of Chartered Accountants in Australia submitted that their commitment to<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is vitally important when dem<strong>on</strong>strating to clients, the business<br />

community and governments the high degree of integrity and professi<strong>on</strong>alism which<br />

members of the Accounting Bodies possess. To this end, the Accounting Bodies have<br />

sought to ensure that these groups can have c<strong>on</strong>fidence in the ethical standing and<br />

technical competence of our members and, in turn, in the quality of various<br />

223 Chapter 3 outlines reas<strong>on</strong>s for self-regulati<strong>on</strong> and the types of schemes adopted. The<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sultant’s report, Tasman Asia Pacific 2000, Analysis of market circumstances where industry<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be most and least effective, also discusses particular industry’s initiating<br />

schemes.<br />

224 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 11, p. 2.<br />

225 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 27, p. 5.<br />

226 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 11, p. 4.<br />

85


accounting, auditing and other assurance and advisory services which the Bodies<br />

provide. 227<br />

This pattern is also evident internati<strong>on</strong>ally. Indeed, internati<strong>on</strong>al experience teaches<br />

that the acti<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>on</strong>e nati<strong>on</strong>al industry associati<strong>on</strong> may act as a catalyst for similar<br />

industries in other countries to follow suit. For example, the Canadian Chemical<br />

Producers’ Associati<strong>on</strong> introduced its Resp<strong>on</strong>sible Care initiative in 1985 and it has<br />

since become a global alliance with over 40 countries participating in the scheme. 228<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that industry will promote self-regulati<strong>on</strong> when there are<br />

reas<strong>on</strong>s to do so, such as to enhance c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence to boost sales or ‘head off’<br />

government regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Role of Government<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> self-regulati<strong>on</strong> by its definiti<strong>on</strong>, is regulati<strong>on</strong> by industry. However,<br />

Government involvement in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can range from general policy guidance<br />

to more interventi<strong>on</strong>ist models. Government is in a positi<strong>on</strong> to identify particular<br />

problems or social policy objectives and can assist in designing a self-regulatory<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>se to address them.<br />

Throughout the inquiry process, the role of government in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> has been a<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tentious issue. Hence, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has focused <strong>on</strong> the role of Government in this<br />

chapter.<br />

Spectrum of Government involvement<br />

As with different types of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, not surprisingly there is a spectrum of<br />

Government involvement ranging from little or no involvement to a more<br />

interventi<strong>on</strong>ist approach. 229<br />

At <strong>on</strong>e end of the spectrum, industry initiatives that improve the amount of<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> available to c<strong>on</strong>sumers to make informed choices might have little or no<br />

Government involvement at all. For example, industry guidelines or customer<br />

service charters fall into this category.<br />

Moving al<strong>on</strong>g the spectrum, standards developed by Standards Australia will often<br />

see Government as a stakeholder providing comments.<br />

‘Light touch’ approaches include the work of the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Divisi<strong>on</strong> in<br />

Treasury and the ACCC in advising schemes <strong>on</strong> voluntary codes. For example the<br />

227 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 33, p. 1.<br />

228 Appendix D, p. 146.<br />

229 For more interventi<strong>on</strong>ist approaches, see Appendix C for further discussi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the regulatory<br />

framework for underpinning codes.<br />

86


ACCC has assisted industry with the <strong>Australian</strong> Code of Practice for Computerised<br />

Checkout Systems in Supermarkets.<br />

Whereas, the Government has incorporated codes into a regulatory framework in<br />

other cases. 230<br />

Similarly, at the internati<strong>on</strong>al level there is a range of government involvement in<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. However, as outlined in Appendix D, Australia appears to be at the<br />

forefr<strong>on</strong>t of internati<strong>on</strong>al policy initiatives to promote regulatory reform and<br />

effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. 231<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> notes that there is currently a range of Government involvement in<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> depending <strong>on</strong> the industry and the particular scheme.<br />

Public policy objectives of Government<br />

The degree of Government involvement in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> will depend <strong>on</strong> the public<br />

policy objective. 232 Government involvement in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is justified when there<br />

is a public policy objective that would otherwise call for a regulatory resp<strong>on</strong>se.<br />

The Instituti<strong>on</strong> of Engineers Australia commented that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is appropriate<br />

as applied to the provisi<strong>on</strong> of some, but not all, engineering services. The Instituti<strong>on</strong><br />

commented that those areas of engineering practice that represent a risk to public<br />

health and safety or where there is a significant asymmetry of knowledge between<br />

the professi<strong>on</strong>al engineer and the c<strong>on</strong>sumer require a co-regulatory approach that<br />

statutorily limits the provisi<strong>on</strong> of certain types of services to competent<br />

practiti<strong>on</strong>ers. 233<br />

On the other hand, the <strong>Australian</strong> Food and Grocery Council commented that the<br />

existence of market failure does not in itself justify Government interventi<strong>on</strong> as the<br />

market may correct itself over time. Government interventi<strong>on</strong> may not be a remedy<br />

to the failure. It suggested that the <strong>on</strong>us of proof in determining whether regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

will correct market failure is <strong>on</strong> the prop<strong>on</strong>ents of the regulati<strong>on</strong>. It also argued that<br />

interventi<strong>on</strong> must provide the highest net benefit to c<strong>on</strong>sumers as individuals, and<br />

the community as a whole. 234<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> also recognises that Government will be involved in aspects of<br />

particular industries. For example, the scope of service delivery in<br />

230 Ibid.<br />

231 Appendix D, p. 146.<br />

232 As discussed in chapter 5, self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is more appropriate where there is no str<strong>on</strong>g public<br />

interest c<strong>on</strong>cern. Examples of public policy objectives are health and safety issues.<br />

233 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 26, p. 23.<br />

234 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 30, p. 2.<br />

87


telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s, and the proposed privacy legislati<strong>on</strong> that will impact across all<br />

industries. 235<br />

As a general principle, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that Government has a role in<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to ensure that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> targets and achieves the relevant public<br />

policy objective.<br />

Government involvement<br />

As discussed elsewhere, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is a three-way<br />

partnership between industry, c<strong>on</strong>sumers and Government.<br />

From an industry perspective, the <strong>Australian</strong> Pharmaceutical Manufacturers<br />

Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that an advantage of their current self-regulatory system is<br />

that it is an outward dem<strong>on</strong>strati<strong>on</strong> of successful partnership and trust between<br />

Government and industry. 236 Similarly, the <strong>Australian</strong> Supermarket Institute<br />

commented that the ACCC has been of great assistance in developing their Code’s<br />

provisi<strong>on</strong>s and ensuring that they have remained relevant and effective. 237<br />

The Financial <strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Service commented that the whole of the<br />

self-regulatory process was satisfactory. Government was quite willing to allow<br />

industry to develop the schemes. The schemes that the Financial <strong>Industry</strong><br />

Complaints Service has been involved with have approval from ASIC and c<strong>on</strong>sult<br />

with Treasury. 238<br />

Cable & Wireless Optus commented that the involvement of regulators as ‘observers’<br />

throughout the process of code and standard development has several benefits. First,<br />

it has enabled the industry to address regulator c<strong>on</strong>cerns at the outset rather than<br />

address issues at the end of the process. Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, it has resulted in regulators being<br />

fully aware of current industry discussi<strong>on</strong>s and hence familiar with the c<strong>on</strong>text for<br />

industry decisi<strong>on</strong>s. 239<br />

Cable & Wireless Optus surmised that in planning for self-regulatory schemes, it is<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sidered beneficial for the roles and resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities of regulators to be clearly<br />

defined at the outset of the process and actively managed to encourage a cooperative<br />

approach. 240<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that Government, am<strong>on</strong>g other roles, is a stakeholder in<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> and can offer assistance in the development and in maintaining the<br />

relevance of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

235 <strong>Draft</strong> Privacy Bill 2000.<br />

236 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 10, p. 5.<br />

237 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 11, p. 7.<br />

238 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 15, p.4.<br />

239 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 6, p. 3.<br />

240 Ibid.<br />

88


Government can promote and assist in the development of<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

The Government has had experience with many industries wishing to introduce<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. It is therefore in a good positi<strong>on</strong> to advise and guide industry in<br />

different ways of approaching self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

By publicising the benefits of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>sumers, the Government may also<br />

be able to help create an incentive for industry to effectively self-regulate.<br />

Maintaining the higher standards required by a self-regulatory scheme may impose<br />

costs <strong>on</strong> businesses which will be reflected in the prices charged to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. If<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers are not well informed about the benefits of dealing with a member of the<br />

self-regulatory scheme, there will be little incentive for businesses to incur the extra<br />

costs required to establish or join the scheme, and those businesses that do so may be<br />

at a competitive disadvantage. Once the scheme wins acceptance within the market,<br />

there should be less need for the Government to maintain its involvement.<br />

The Insurance Council of Australia commented that it is important for Government<br />

to be supportive of self-regulatory codes and schemes, and to promote and<br />

encourage c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence in their use and effectiveness. The Council<br />

commented that Government could assist industry in the development of<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> by promoting a more informed understanding of the role and scope of<br />

industry codes am<strong>on</strong>g c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups. It is particularly important to promote an<br />

understanding of the value of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> when it provides a more effective<br />

alternative to legislati<strong>on</strong> for both c<strong>on</strong>sumers and industry. The Council argued that<br />

having formally approved a code, by a sufficiently transparent process, Government<br />

should become a supporter of its aims and objectives. 241<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Chamber of Commerce and <strong>Industry</strong> also urged Government to<br />

address c<strong>on</strong>sumer scepticism of industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> through educati<strong>on</strong> and<br />

promoti<strong>on</strong> of successful self-regulatory schemes. 242<br />

Further, the <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

educati<strong>on</strong> should be pursued jointly with industry groups using the resources of<br />

Government and industry. 243<br />

The Government has also promoted self-regulati<strong>on</strong> through guidelines, directories<br />

and the Internet. For example, the Business Entry Point will c<strong>on</strong>tain a database of<br />

codes across Australia. 244 Similarly, the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth’s Directory of C<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Schemes and Complaint Handling Organisati<strong>on</strong>s sets out c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

241 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 18, pp. 7-8.<br />

242 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 27, p. 12.<br />

243 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 36, p. 8.<br />

244 The Business Entry Point site can be accessed via http://www.business.gov.au. The Business<br />

Entry Point provides businesses with access to resources from approximately 50<br />

Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Government agencies, 100 State and Territory agencies and 125 industry<br />

associati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

89


dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes, complaint handling organisati<strong>on</strong>s and other useful<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tacts such as fair-trading agencies. 245<br />

As discussed in chapter 6, the Government has also released a publicati<strong>on</strong> titled<br />

Benchmarks for <strong>Industry</strong>-based Customer Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Schemes which is a guide to<br />

industry in designing and improving such schemes. 246 The Benchmarks were<br />

developed to apply primarily to nati<strong>on</strong>ally based customer dispute schemes set up<br />

under the auspices of an industry. However, the underlying policy principles have<br />

also proven useful to smaller and n<strong>on</strong>-industry schemes.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> notes that the Minister for Financial Services and Regulati<strong>on</strong> is<br />

committed to reviewing the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth’s Benchmarks for <strong>Industry</strong>-based Customer<br />

Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Schemes this year.<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s Authority has also produced its own guide, titled<br />

Developing telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s codes for registrati<strong>on</strong>, which addresses its approach to<br />

assessing codes for registrati<strong>on</strong>. The Authority commented that it has received<br />

positive feedback from ACIF and industry players about the clarity and<br />

comprehensiveness of the guide. 247<br />

Similarly, the Office of Small Business produced Resolving Small Business Disputes,<br />

which it commends as a resource for examining issues around self-regulatory<br />

approaches to dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>. 248<br />

The ACCC has also produced guidelines to assist industry with compliance and the<br />

authorisati<strong>on</strong> process. 249 Similarly, ASIC commented that it has also engaged in a<br />

range of activities aimed at promoting alternative dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> processes in the<br />

financial services industry. This includes chairing the Complaints Scheme<br />

Roundtable which provides a forum for the promoti<strong>on</strong> and support of complaints<br />

schemes in the sector. 250<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that Government can have a role to play in the development,<br />

and promoti<strong>on</strong>, of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

245 C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Divisi<strong>on</strong>, Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Department of Treasury 2000, Directory of<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Schemes and Complaint Handling Organisati<strong>on</strong>s, 4th editi<strong>on</strong>, released<br />

by the Minister for Financial Services & Regulati<strong>on</strong>, the H<strong>on</strong> Joe Hockey MP. This document is<br />

available <strong>on</strong> the Internet at http://www.treasury.gov.au/publicati<strong>on</strong>s/pubs.asp.<br />

246 Benchmarks for <strong>Industry</strong>-based Customer Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Schemes 1997, released by the then<br />

Minister for Customs and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs, Senator the H<strong>on</strong> Chris Ellis<strong>on</strong>. This publicati<strong>on</strong><br />

can be accessed through the Treasury web-site: www.treasury.gov.au/publicati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

247 This guide is available from the <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s Authority or through the Internet<br />

at: http://www.aca.gov.au/codes/.<br />

248 Available from the Office of Small Business or<br />

http://www.dewrsb.gov.au/group_osb/smallbus/resolvedisp/index.htm.<br />

249 For more informati<strong>on</strong> visit the ACCC website at: http://www.accc.gov.au.<br />

250 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 5.<br />

90


Integrati<strong>on</strong> into the regulatory regime and internati<strong>on</strong>al harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong><br />

Government also has a role to assist in ensuring that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is integrated into<br />

the regulatory framework within and outside Australia. Government is in a good<br />

positi<strong>on</strong> to promote internati<strong>on</strong>al cooperati<strong>on</strong> and harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of self-regulatory<br />

schemes.<br />

For example, the <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s Authority stated that Government<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> protects against inc<strong>on</strong>sistency with legislati<strong>on</strong>. For example, the<br />

Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Act 1997, Trade Practices Act 1974, Privacy Act 1988, Disability<br />

Discriminati<strong>on</strong> Act 1992 and State fair trading legislati<strong>on</strong> may all have implicati<strong>on</strong>s for<br />

codes, as may various instruments setting out provisi<strong>on</strong>s or standards that must be<br />

adhered to. The Authority argued that representati<strong>on</strong> by government agencies<br />

ensures that legislative advice is available at the code development stage. 251<br />

ASIC also commented that Government can assist in the process of developing<br />

schemes — this will include providing informati<strong>on</strong> and advice designed to ensure<br />

that the schemes are properly integrated into the regulatory framework. ASIC<br />

commented that it has extensive experience in dealing with a range of self-regulatory<br />

mechanisms that can be brought to bear during the c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> of any<br />

self-regulatory scheme. 252<br />

NRMA stated that an important role for Government is to work with State<br />

Governments and industry to try to ensure that Federal and State based codes that<br />

apply to the same or similar products are as uniform as possible. This will reduce<br />

compliance costs, which is a particularly important issue as many companies start to<br />

market their products and services nati<strong>on</strong>ally. C<strong>on</strong>sumers would also benefit<br />

through simpler and more standardised guidelines and codes. 253<br />

The Associati<strong>on</strong> of Superannuati<strong>on</strong> Funds of Australia Limited commented that ad<br />

hoc or differing codes and standards or poorly designed regulati<strong>on</strong>s or laws can<br />

significantly increase the overheads to industry (and to final c<strong>on</strong>sumers). It<br />

commented that increased overheads can be the outcome where state laws apply. 254<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> also recognises that Australia is part of a bigger game, and<br />

self-regulatory schemes should be aware of overseas standards. For example,<br />

Standards Australia commented that c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> of regulati<strong>on</strong> versus<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> must be written within a framework of encouraging and facilitating<br />

global trade. 255<br />

251 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 17, p. 5.<br />

252 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 32.<br />

253 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 7, p. 5.<br />

254 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 22, p. 4.<br />

255 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 13, p. 1.<br />

91


Similarly, the <strong>Australian</strong> Toy Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that any imposts or obligati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>on</strong> companies under any self-regulatory arrangement should not disadvantage<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> companies vis-à-vis internati<strong>on</strong>al competiti<strong>on</strong>. 256<br />

NRMA also stated that with the increasingly globalised nature of many markets and<br />

the growth of e-commerce, the Government also has an important role to play in<br />

working to achieve internati<strong>on</strong>al harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>sumers would then receive the<br />

same level of protecti<strong>on</strong> in each market. C<strong>on</strong>versely, it will help to prevent<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> businesses from losing customers to overseas countries that may offer<br />

cheaper products but provide less c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> through industry<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. 257<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that Government can assist industry in developing and<br />

maintaining the relevance of self-regulatory schemes by raising awareness of the<br />

regulatory framework operating within and outside Australia.<br />

Is Government just cost-shifting?<br />

Some organisati<strong>on</strong>s have argued that government is simply shifting the cost of<br />

regulating <strong>on</strong>to industry. For example, the <strong>Australian</strong> Food and Grocery Council<br />

commented that it does not support self-regulatory measures that are simply seeking<br />

to shift the regulatory resource costs forcing industry to accept the c<strong>on</strong>tingent<br />

liability of developing and maintaining a regulatory measure. 258<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that self-regulatory schemes should be developed and<br />

assessed using the fundamental principles flagged in this report, in other words<br />

identificati<strong>on</strong> of the specific problem and objective, c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>, assessment of the<br />

benefits and costs and the applicati<strong>on</strong> of the effective minimum soluti<strong>on</strong> to the<br />

specific problem.<br />

Regulatory creep<br />

During the c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s, some organisati<strong>on</strong>s raised the issue of regulatory creep.<br />

That is, where self-regulati<strong>on</strong> develops into more quasi-regulati<strong>on</strong> or co-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

This issue was also flagged in the Grey-letter Law report, which stated that ‘those<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sulted raised c<strong>on</strong>cerns that sometimes what starts out as self-regulati<strong>on</strong> can<br />

become widely accepted practice, gain an imprimatur from a government agency,<br />

and then become embodied in a quasi-regulatory arrangement, and may become<br />

black letter law’. 259<br />

Similarly, the <strong>Australian</strong> Chamber of Commerce and <strong>Industry</strong> commented that it is<br />

c<strong>on</strong>cerned about the potential for self-regulatory schemes to become<br />

256 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 23, p. 3.<br />

257 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 7, p. 6.<br />

258 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 30, p. 6.<br />

259 Grey-letter Law: <strong>Report</strong> of the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Interdepartmental Committee <strong>on</strong> Quasi-regulati<strong>on</strong>, 1997,<br />

p. XIV. The report is available at: http://www.pc.gov.au/orr/.<br />

92


quasi-regulati<strong>on</strong>. Often if a scheme appears to be working well, there has been a<br />

tendency for governments to want to formalise it thereby changing the nature of the<br />

self-regulatory industry approach. Many incidents occur and are managed under<br />

self-regulatory schemes without the need to involve the regulator. The <strong>Australian</strong><br />

Chamber of Commerce and <strong>Industry</strong> commented that this is a difficult issue to<br />

address especially when there is a prevalent view am<strong>on</strong>g secti<strong>on</strong>s of the community<br />

that <strong>on</strong>ly regulati<strong>on</strong> is a sufficient safeguard. 260<br />

As a general principle, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that Government should <strong>on</strong>ly be<br />

involved in schemes when there is a public policy objective to do so. If self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

is working well, then there is no need for any, or more, Government involvement. As<br />

noted above, Government can assist in promoting the benefits of self-regulatory<br />

schemes to c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

Government can assist in the analysis of systemic issues<br />

Government can also play a role in the analysis of systemic issues. At the more<br />

interventi<strong>on</strong>ist end of the self-regulatory spectrum, some schemes may be handling<br />

complex and/or a large number of c<strong>on</strong>sumer complaints. Where appropriate, the<br />

Government can assist in the analysis of systemic issues arising from these<br />

complaints. Government can also assist in facilitating the design of a self-regulatory<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>se to address those systemic issues.<br />

The C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre of Victoria, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit Legal Service (Vic) and the<br />

Financial and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Rights Council (Vic) commented that it is inherently<br />

difficult for industries to step back from their business to see systemic issues. They<br />

suggested that <strong>on</strong>e of the primary strengths of a co-regulatory rather than<br />

self-regulatory approach is the ability to build in processes to identify systemic issues<br />

within an industry. Within co-regulatory models this presently best occurs through<br />

industry based external alternative dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes or direct regulatory<br />

oversight. 261<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that, where appropriate, government can assist in the<br />

analysis of systemic issues.<br />

Degree of Government involvement in m<strong>on</strong>itoring self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

There is a range of opti<strong>on</strong>s to m<strong>on</strong>itor self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, including some form of<br />

government involvement. To a large extent, the degree of government involvement<br />

in m<strong>on</strong>itoring will depend <strong>on</strong> the industry c<strong>on</strong>cerned, the nature of the industry<br />

specific problem and the importance of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> meeting its aims. Government<br />

can also underpin schemes in legislati<strong>on</strong> to improve their effectiveness. 262<br />

260 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 27, p. 6.<br />

261 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 29, p. 13.<br />

262 See Appendix C regarding the regulatory framework for underpinning codes.<br />

93


As a broad principle, the Investment and Financial Services Associati<strong>on</strong> supported<br />

the view expressed in the Grey-letter Law report (1997, p. 81) that ‘Government<br />

should not, however, be directly involved in the m<strong>on</strong>itoring and review of schemes<br />

which are self-regulatory. Otherwise, the essential character of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> may be<br />

lost. Government involvement may change the character of the self-regulatory<br />

scheme to <strong>on</strong>e of quasi-regulati<strong>on</strong>.’ 263<br />

Similarly, the <strong>Australian</strong> Chamber of Commerce and <strong>Industry</strong> noted that many<br />

incidents occur and are managed under self-regulatory schemes without the need to<br />

involve the regulator. 264<br />

However, ASIC commented that there is a role for government, in some cases, to<br />

m<strong>on</strong>itor compliance with the code, and assist in the process of reviewing the<br />

operati<strong>on</strong> of self-regulatory schemes, which may lead to alterati<strong>on</strong>s to the scheme or<br />

to other regulatory resp<strong>on</strong>ses (e.g. regulator-issued standards to law reform<br />

recommendati<strong>on</strong>s). 265<br />

ASIC argued that the capacity for timely regulator interventi<strong>on</strong> is especially<br />

important in the case of financial services because the industry is heavily dependent<br />

<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence. If the regulator does not possess the power to intervene in a<br />

timely fashi<strong>on</strong> in the case of market failure, c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fidence in the integrity of<br />

the <strong>Australian</strong> financial markets may be compromised. 266<br />

Similarly, PowerTel commented that any effective self-regulatory regime needs to<br />

recognise that ‘blackspots’ will emerge and government regulators must be<br />

empowered to take remedial acti<strong>on</strong> quickly. 267<br />

The Royal Aer<strong>on</strong>autical Society also argued that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> must always be<br />

accompanied by a rigorous system of dialogue with, and policing by, the<br />

government agency resp<strong>on</strong>sible for the safety of the public. 268<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that there is a role for<br />

government to channel complaints to appropriate industry bodies and m<strong>on</strong>itor the<br />

effectiveness of industry-based complaints handling. This will encourage a<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tinuous dialogue between Government and the private sector in the interest of<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. 269<br />

One observer suggested that ‘Government should be m<strong>on</strong>itoring in a helicopter’. 270<br />

263 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 41, p. 3.<br />

264 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 27, p. 6.<br />

265 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, pp. 32-33.<br />

266 Ibid.<br />

267 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 9, p. 5.<br />

268 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 40, p. 4.<br />

269 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 36, p. 8.<br />

270 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with <strong>Australian</strong> Business Limited, Sydney, 1 March 2000.<br />

94


As a general principle, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that the degree of m<strong>on</strong>itoring by<br />

government will depend <strong>on</strong> the degree of market failure and the c<strong>on</strong>sequences of<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> failing to achieve its objectives. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that<br />

government has an interest in the review of schemes, and can ‘step up’ if<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is failing and can help assess whether self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the most<br />

appropriate mechanism.<br />

Authorisati<strong>on</strong> process<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> should be aware of the authorisati<strong>on</strong> process. 271 As noted by the <strong>Australian</strong><br />

Food and Grocery Council, government also has a role in ensuring that markets are<br />

sufficiently competitive and that firms do not enter into arrangements that lessen the<br />

degree of competiti<strong>on</strong>. 272<br />

The Department of <strong>Industry</strong> Science and Resources commented that self-regulatory<br />

initiatives attempt to create an informal set of industry standards of behaviour. In<br />

most circumstances this has a positive outcome, reducing circumstances of<br />

undesirable c<strong>on</strong>duct and providing a better interface between an industry and its<br />

market. There is a risk, however, that self-regulatory initiatives can give rise to<br />

anti-competitive behaviour, by either suppressing competiti<strong>on</strong> between firms, broad<br />

agreements <strong>on</strong> prices or by forming defacto industry cartels which c<strong>on</strong>solidate<br />

market power. The Department commented that during the drafting of the Oilcode,<br />

for example, c<strong>on</strong>siderable efforts had to be expended to avoid the code entering the<br />

area of price setting or market structure, both areas where potentially<br />

anti-competitive c<strong>on</strong>duct could arise. 273<br />

Similarly, the Department of <strong>Industry</strong> Science and Resources argued that<br />

self-regulatory initiatives in the form of design standards can be used to establish<br />

effective barriers to entry in a marketplace, entrenching the positi<strong>on</strong> of existing<br />

market participants against the interests of new market entrants. Initiatives <strong>on</strong><br />

product quality can, while couched in the interests of c<strong>on</strong>sumers, c<strong>on</strong>tribute to the<br />

establishment of a protected market which may not be in c<strong>on</strong>sumers’ ultimate<br />

interest. 274<br />

The Department of <strong>Industry</strong>, Science and Resources submitted that, while the ACCC<br />

m<strong>on</strong>itors anti-competitive arrangements, and acts where it can be shown that such<br />

arrangements are not in the public interest, c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> needs to be taken in the<br />

preparati<strong>on</strong> of self-regulatory initiatives to minimise anti-competitive effects. 275<br />

During the course of the inquiry, some industry associati<strong>on</strong>s raised some c<strong>on</strong>cerns<br />

over the authorisati<strong>on</strong> process. One industry associati<strong>on</strong> commented that<br />

271 Chapter 6 discusses the authorisati<strong>on</strong> process.<br />

272 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 30, p. 2.<br />

273 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 31, pp. 19-20.<br />

274 Ibid.<br />

275 Ibid.<br />

95


authorisati<strong>on</strong> fees are potentially a deterrent for smaller associati<strong>on</strong>s. 276 At present,<br />

there is no discreti<strong>on</strong> under the Trade Practices Act 1974 for the ACCC to waive fees.<br />

However, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> notes that under the nati<strong>on</strong>al competiti<strong>on</strong> policy review<br />

process, the Government is committed to reviewing fees (including the authorisati<strong>on</strong><br />

fee) charged under the Trade Practices Act 1974 this year.<br />

Another associati<strong>on</strong> that has been through the authorisati<strong>on</strong> process, the <strong>Australian</strong><br />

Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong>, commented that the process needs to be more clearly<br />

defined. The associati<strong>on</strong> submitted that time limits should be placed <strong>on</strong> public<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>, that it was not the role of the process to redesign or redraft industry<br />

documents, and that the applicant should be c<strong>on</strong>sulted <strong>on</strong> the c<strong>on</strong>tent and c<strong>on</strong>text of<br />

any public announcement regarding the applicati<strong>on</strong>. 277<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has made the ACCC aware of these c<strong>on</strong>cerns.<br />

However, overall, organisati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>sulted found the authorisati<strong>on</strong> process useful<br />

and a necessary process for protecting competiti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that the authorisati<strong>on</strong> process is essential in providing a<br />

public benefit justificati<strong>on</strong> process. However, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that industry<br />

should manage the risk of having to seek authorisati<strong>on</strong> in the first place.<br />

Centralising Government resp<strong>on</strong>sibility<br />

During the course of c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s, a number of organisati<strong>on</strong>s raised the issue of<br />

centralising resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for self-regulati<strong>on</strong> into <strong>on</strong>e Government agency. Some<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>sidered that it was c<strong>on</strong>fusing and bureaucratic for industry to know<br />

which regulator(s) to deal with. For example, the Service Providers <strong>Industry</strong><br />

Associati<strong>on</strong> (SPAN) commented that regulatory oversight of informati<strong>on</strong> industries<br />

is fragmented across many agencies and organisati<strong>on</strong>s. It submitted that<br />

industry-specific regulati<strong>on</strong> applicable to telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s service providers<br />

involves:<br />

¾ The Department of Communicati<strong>on</strong>s, Informati<strong>on</strong> Technology and the Arts;<br />

¾ The <strong>Australian</strong> Broadcasting Authority;<br />

¾ The <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s Authority;<br />

¾ The ACCC;<br />

¾ The Attorney-General’s Department (privacy, intercepti<strong>on</strong> etc.);<br />

¾ The <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Forum (the principal self-regulatory<br />

resource for the industry);<br />

276 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the Internet <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong>, Canberra, 6 March 2000.<br />

277 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 36, p. 9.<br />

96


¾ The Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman; and<br />

¾ The <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s Access Forum. 278<br />

SPAN commented that coupled with a variety of other agencies that administer<br />

generic industry and c<strong>on</strong>sumer codes and legislati<strong>on</strong>, as well as industry associati<strong>on</strong><br />

codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct, the totality represents a complex web of requirements to be<br />

understood and followed by industry participants. 279<br />

SPAN argued for clear allocati<strong>on</strong> of areas of resp<strong>on</strong>sibility to lead agencies,<br />

expressed in simple terms that are widely understood and respected by government,<br />

industry and c<strong>on</strong>sumer interests. Those lead agencies should set the basic regulatory<br />

principles that guide regulatory and self-regulatory activities (an example is the<br />

establishment of Privacy Principles by the Attorney-General and Privacy<br />

Commissi<strong>on</strong>er, c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> would be presumably handled by the<br />

Treasury). 280<br />

Similarly, NRMA commented that another acti<strong>on</strong> by Government that could help to<br />

promote more effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong> would be to establish a specialised Unit<br />

within a department such as Treasury to deal with self-regulatory issues. This would<br />

help to ensure a c<strong>on</strong>sistent approach to self-regulati<strong>on</strong> by Government as well as<br />

streamline the administrative process for business and c<strong>on</strong>sumers. 281<br />

However, Government agencies argued that each agency has its own specialised area<br />

and to try to centralise this expertise would be futile. 282 For example, as noted above,<br />

ASIC has resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for the financial sector whereas the Department of Health<br />

and Aged Care oversees the health industry. The agencies argued that a centralised<br />

agency dealing with self-regulati<strong>on</strong> would lead to <strong>on</strong>e big, bureaucratic organisati<strong>on</strong><br />

which would be detrimental to industry.<br />

To some extent, the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Divisi<strong>on</strong> in Treasury does offer industry<br />

advice <strong>on</strong> developing codes of practice in the first instance. This advice revolves<br />

around the Codes Kit c<strong>on</strong>taining previously menti<strong>on</strong>ed publicati<strong>on</strong>s such as the Codes<br />

of C<strong>on</strong>duct Policy Framework and Benchmarks for <strong>Industry</strong>-based Customer Dispute<br />

Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Schemes. 283 In additi<strong>on</strong>, the ACCC also assists self-regulatory schemes,<br />

particularly with compliance and enforcement.<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that centralising Government resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> would result in a loss of expertise. However, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders<br />

278 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 25, pp. 2-3.<br />

279 Ibid.<br />

280 Ibid.<br />

281 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 7, p. 6.<br />

282 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with Government agencies held in Canberra, 6 December 1999.<br />

283 Codes of C<strong>on</strong>duct Policy Framework released by the then Minister for Customs and C<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

Affairs in March 1998; this document is available <strong>on</strong> the Internet at<br />

http://www.treasury.gov.au (choose C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs/Publicati<strong>on</strong>s/<strong>Industry</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-Regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

Publicati<strong>on</strong>s).<br />

97


that Government needs to ensure Departmental and agency roles in self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

are clear.<br />

Role of c<strong>on</strong>sumers<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups play an important role in developing<br />

and maintaining the relevance of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. A number of organisati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

(including industry, c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups and Government agencies) have expressed the<br />

importance of c<strong>on</strong>sumer participati<strong>on</strong> in adding credibility to self-regulatory<br />

schemes.<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s Authority commented that c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups and the public is <strong>on</strong>e of the most important requirements of<br />

developing a telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s code for registrati<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with these<br />

groups is assured by Part 6 of the Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Act 1992 which requires the<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Forum (ACIF) to c<strong>on</strong>sult with at least <strong>on</strong>e<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer representative organisati<strong>on</strong>, and obliges ACIF to also provide a minimum<br />

30 day c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> period for comments from the public. In practice, ACIF usually<br />

provides a 45 day c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumer codes. 284<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s Authority suggested that c<strong>on</strong>sumer organisati<strong>on</strong>s in<br />

particular have made a very significant c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to the development of ACIF<br />

codes. C<strong>on</strong>sumer representatives participate <strong>on</strong> all six C<strong>on</strong>sumer Codes Reference<br />

Panel Working Committees and advise <strong>on</strong> all c<strong>on</strong>sumer issues which arise in code<br />

development. 285<br />

It also commented that c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups and representatives have been instrumental<br />

in determining the priorities and work programme of the ACIF C<strong>on</strong>sumer Codes<br />

Reference Panel. The Authority commented that they have made significant research<br />

and policy c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s to the work of the Reference Panel, both in terms of sharing<br />

results of research undertaken under the auspices of other organisati<strong>on</strong>s and<br />

instituti<strong>on</strong>s, and in undertaking c<strong>on</strong>tracted research and policy work <strong>on</strong> ACIF’s<br />

behalf. During the public comment phase c<strong>on</strong>sumer representatives provide advice<br />

<strong>on</strong> targeting interested groups and utilising networks to distribute informati<strong>on</strong> about<br />

the draft code. 286<br />

Similarly, the Department of Health and Aged Care commented that c<strong>on</strong>sumers are<br />

becoming sceptical when they perceive self-regulati<strong>on</strong> imposed as a cheap opti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

and for the benefit of business. The Department argued that, overall, if<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is to work effectively, there needs to be c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> of how to<br />

encourage str<strong>on</strong>g community involvement to ensure it remains open to rigorous,<br />

public scrutiny. In this c<strong>on</strong>text it is worth noting the level of public debate involving<br />

284 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 17, p. 7.<br />

285 Ibid.<br />

286 Ibid.<br />

98


the passage of sensitive primary legislati<strong>on</strong> through Parliament. Overall, there is a<br />

need for a clearer picture, or at least guidelines, <strong>on</strong> the role of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

supporting genuine tripartite soluti<strong>on</strong>s. If such developments do not occur, we risk<br />

seeing declining c<strong>on</strong>sumer faith in self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, and other useful alternative forms<br />

of regulati<strong>on</strong> (such as public health promoti<strong>on</strong>al activities). 287<br />

Similarly, industry bodies have acknowledged the importance of c<strong>on</strong>sumer input.<br />

For example, the Insurance Council of Australia recognised the necessary role to be<br />

played by c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups in the development and maintenance of effective<br />

industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. 288 Likewise, the Financial <strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Service<br />

commented that c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups have been part of the working party for the<br />

development of their scheme. It suggested that it is important that the general public<br />

has c<strong>on</strong>fidence in the schemes and c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups assist in providing this. 289<br />

The C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre of Victoria, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit Legal Service (Vic) and the<br />

Financial and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Rights Council (Vic) commented that in order to deliver<br />

outcomes which serve the interests of c<strong>on</strong>sumers as well as industry it is necessary to<br />

include expert c<strong>on</strong>sumer advocacy and participati<strong>on</strong> in the development and<br />

oversight of co-regulatory schemes or models. 290<br />

The C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre of Victoria, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit Legal Service (Vic) and the<br />

Financial and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Rights Council (Vic) endorse c<strong>on</strong>sumer participati<strong>on</strong> in the<br />

following processes:<br />

¾ Government and regulatory c<strong>on</strong>sultative processes;<br />

¾ public hearing and enquiries;<br />

¾ the development, amendment and review of industry standards and c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

of service and supply;<br />

¾ the development of c<strong>on</strong>sumer friendly products and services;<br />

¾ the development of codes, charters and dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms; and<br />

¾ the oversight and management of external dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes. 291<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> also recognises that c<strong>on</strong>sumer participati<strong>on</strong> is c<strong>on</strong>strained by limited<br />

resources. For example, the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre of Victoria, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit<br />

Legal Service (Vic) and the Financial and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Rights Council (Vic) commented<br />

that c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups and c<strong>on</strong>sumers generally are largely under-resourced in terms<br />

of time and funding, both of which are necessary to meaningfully participate. This is<br />

287 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 44, p. 13.<br />

288 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 18, p. 7.<br />

289 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 15, p. 4.<br />

290 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 29, p. 14.<br />

291 Ibid.<br />

99


particularly the case when compared to the resources generally available to industry<br />

participants. The C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre of Victoria, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit Legal Service<br />

(Vic) and the Financial and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Rights Council (Vic) argued that as part of the<br />

examinati<strong>on</strong> of specific industries proposing to move to a less prescriptive regulatory<br />

model, industries should be required to propose models for the inclusi<strong>on</strong> of<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer representatives. That representati<strong>on</strong> should be proporti<strong>on</strong>al with industry<br />

participati<strong>on</strong>. 292<br />

Similarly, the C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Network commented that there are<br />

resource implicati<strong>on</strong>s in meeting the demand for c<strong>on</strong>sumer input arising from many<br />

different sources. Organisati<strong>on</strong>s such as themselves which rely substantially <strong>on</strong><br />

volunteer c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s find it increasingly difficult to attract and retain sufficient<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer representatives to meet the needs of the various regulatory and<br />

self-regulatory bodies. 293<br />

Further, NSW Legal Aid argued that, as noted in the Grey-letter Law report, there<br />

needs to be effective resourcing provided to c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups to participate in the<br />

drafting and subsequent reviews of codes, and in the bodies resp<strong>on</strong>sible for<br />

overseeing the code. 294<br />

NSW Legal Aid commented that if self-regulatory or co-regulatory schemes are to<br />

work properly and deliver the benefits envisaged, then there needs to be effective<br />

participati<strong>on</strong> of c<strong>on</strong>sumer representatives and, therefore, a commitment by<br />

Government to properly resourcing those representatives. 295<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong> recommended that a levy be imposed <strong>on</strong> the<br />

supply side of the market of other industries to ensure appropriate demand side<br />

input. 296<br />

The Small Enterprise Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Centre Limited (SETEL) noted that<br />

Government grant funding has enabled c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups to adopt a broader focus<br />

<strong>on</strong> telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s issues and to participate in self-regulatory forums. 297<br />

SETEL commented that the ‘voice’ of c<strong>on</strong>sumers has been strengthened through this<br />

process and the involvement in the self-regulatory process has enabled the<br />

presentati<strong>on</strong> of the various c<strong>on</strong>sumer perspectives to a wider audience in the<br />

telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s industry. The major discrepancy existing today is the imbalance<br />

of input into the self-regulatory process caused by restricti<strong>on</strong>s in funding of<br />

292 Ibid.<br />

293 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 32, p. 2.<br />

294 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 24, p. 6.<br />

295 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 24, p. 6.<br />

296 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 16, p. 2.<br />

297 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 20, pp. 2-4.<br />

100


c<strong>on</strong>sumer representati<strong>on</strong> so as to be able to ‘compete’ with the input (and influence)<br />

of the industry representatives. 298<br />

SETEL also c<strong>on</strong>tended that the self-regulatory model used in the telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

industry in particular, pits some of Australia’s most powerful corporati<strong>on</strong>s against<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer representatives in a frequently unequal battle. It believed that the funding<br />

of c<strong>on</strong>sumer representati<strong>on</strong> in any self-regulating industry should be commensurate<br />

with the size and resources of the industry and the extent to which c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

representati<strong>on</strong> is required in self-regulatory forums. 299<br />

In other words, SETEL argued that ‘David must at least have a sling and a st<strong>on</strong>e<br />

when going in to battle with Goliath’. 300<br />

ASIC also argued that c<strong>on</strong>sumer organisati<strong>on</strong>s would require access to sufficient<br />

resources if they were to c<strong>on</strong>tribute effectively to the process of developing<br />

self-regulatory schemes. 301<br />

At the internati<strong>on</strong>al level, other countries (for example, the United Kingdom and<br />

Canada) also acknowledge the valuable c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> that c<strong>on</strong>sumers can make to<br />

successful self-regulatory schemes. 302<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups, and c<strong>on</strong>sumer participati<strong>on</strong> more<br />

generally, assume an important role in the development and in maintaining the<br />

relevance of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> also recognises that c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

participati<strong>on</strong> will be limited by human and financial resource c<strong>on</strong>straints if there is<br />

no external assistance forthcoming.<br />

Oversight committee<br />

During the course of c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> has heard a number of<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>s advocating for an oversight committee for self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. For example,<br />

the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Advisory Council commented that in a<br />

maintenance and m<strong>on</strong>itoring role, the Government could create a small ‘Code’<br />

authority independently reporting annually <strong>on</strong> the performance of endorsed codes<br />

(award schemes etc), innovati<strong>on</strong>s and shortcomings. It would also be resp<strong>on</strong>sible for<br />

endorsement and public educati<strong>on</strong>. The Advisory Council discussed that this may be<br />

able to be achieved at effectively no cost by redirecting existing ASIC and/or ACCC<br />

funds being applied to self-regulati<strong>on</strong> issues. 303<br />

298 Ibid.<br />

299 Ibid.<br />

300 Ibid.<br />

301 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 13.<br />

302 Appendix D, p. 145.<br />

303 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 14, p. 6.<br />

101


Similarly, the <strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong> cited that while a lot of effort goes<br />

into the formati<strong>on</strong> of self-regulatory standards, this diligence is rarely followed<br />

through in practice. For example, it submitted that a series of recommendati<strong>on</strong>s from<br />

a review have not been implemented. The Associati<strong>on</strong> would support the<br />

recommendati<strong>on</strong> to create a tri-partisan (government, c<strong>on</strong>sumers and industry)<br />

oversight committee that would seek to ensure self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is not <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

implemented but also maintained. 304<br />

Further, Clayt<strong>on</strong> Utz commented that a body could be resp<strong>on</strong>sible for administering<br />

the codes and liaising with industry bodies to ensure that the various codes are<br />

reviewed and amended where appropriate at regular intervals. This body could also<br />

be resp<strong>on</strong>sible for maintaining a code register website and interacting with bodies<br />

that are proposed to perform similar functi<strong>on</strong>s under legislati<strong>on</strong> such as the Privacy<br />

Commissi<strong>on</strong>er. It commented that to ensure the regulatory burden imposed by such<br />

administrati<strong>on</strong> is not too heavy <strong>on</strong> code subscribers it is recommended that such an<br />

administrator’s role be ‘light handed’ and facilitative rather than compelling. 305<br />

However, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises from an industry perspective, some form of<br />

oversight committee would add an extra level of bureaucracy that industry has to<br />

deal with. Further, to a large extent, the Government already plays a role in<br />

m<strong>on</strong>itoring self-regulati<strong>on</strong> and ensuring that it is still relevant.<br />

304 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 16, p. 2.<br />

305 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 43, p. 3.<br />

102


Developing a model code of practice<br />

As discussed elsewhere, there is no single industry model of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

However, there are elements of good practice in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> that are generally<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sistent across schemes. 306 Some organisati<strong>on</strong>s have argued that a model code<br />

could be developed al<strong>on</strong>g these elements of good practice.<br />

Clayt<strong>on</strong> Utz commented that there should be uniform requirements for codes. It<br />

discussed the establishment of a register for codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct, where a quality<br />

assessment procedure could be implemented to ensure that a particular code was<br />

appropriate for inclusi<strong>on</strong> in the register. To this end, a set of core requirements<br />

should be developed and finalised as being necessarily evident in each code<br />

appearing in the register as well as ensuring a degree of uniformity between different<br />

codes. 307<br />

Clayt<strong>on</strong> Utz suggested that such core requirements should include:<br />

¾ complaint handling and dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> procedures which comply with<br />

AS4269 (the <strong>Australian</strong> Standard <strong>on</strong> complaints handling);<br />

¾ sancti<strong>on</strong>s and penalties appropriate to the industry for deliberate and<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tinuous breaches of the code;<br />

¾ the informati<strong>on</strong> privacy principles (where appropriate);<br />

¾ provisi<strong>on</strong>s dealing with transacti<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>ducted via electr<strong>on</strong>ic commerce (where<br />

applicable); and<br />

¾ procedures for the regular review and amendment of the code.<br />

Clayt<strong>on</strong> Utz argued that by making code provisi<strong>on</strong>s more uniform, industry<br />

participants which are regulated by multiple codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct can achieve<br />

compliance more effectively without needing to develop multiple code compliance<br />

systems. 308<br />

Similarly, the <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that the role of<br />

Government in respect of codes should be to both promote nati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>sistency by<br />

developing model codes under the auspices of (for example) the Ministerial Council<br />

<strong>on</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs, where appropriate, and to encourage self-regulatory industry<br />

bodies to develop codes based <strong>on</strong> the model. 309<br />

306 See chapter 6.<br />

307 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 43, p. 2.<br />

308 Ibid.<br />

309 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 36, p. 8.<br />

103


Further, the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Advisory Council suggested that<br />

there is a role for Government in establishing a Government endorsed ‘Code’<br />

framework (developed through <strong>Australian</strong> Standards). It argued that <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

participants in codes who meet the requirements can advertise that fact, and<br />

participants in codes must advertise that their code does not meet the requirements.<br />

Participants in an industry with a complying code who do not subscribe should<br />

advertise the fact. The Advisory Council suggested that part of the endorsement<br />

process would involve the examinati<strong>on</strong> of competiti<strong>on</strong> issues, for example cartels of<br />

big players c<strong>on</strong>structing codes which may have the effect of forcing out smaller<br />

players. 310<br />

As discussed throughout the report, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders there is no single<br />

industry model for self-regulati<strong>on</strong> or codes. However, there are some general<br />

principles of good practice as discussed in chapter 6. 311<br />

310 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 14, p. 6.<br />

311 The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> also recognises that the Ministerial Council of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs guideline 1996,<br />

Fair Trading Codes of C<strong>on</strong>duct, Why have them, how to prepare them is a useful reference tool for<br />

industry developing codes.<br />

104


Chapter 8<br />

Opti<strong>on</strong>s that facilitate the improvement and<br />

harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> is to inquire into and report <strong>on</strong> opti<strong>on</strong>s that facilitate the improvement<br />

and harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes while reducing costs to industry<br />

and improving outcomes for c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

Effective dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> is a crucial element of industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> offering<br />

redress to c<strong>on</strong>sumers and it can also identify systemic problems in the industry.<br />

Dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes are an excellent m<strong>on</strong>itoring tool increasing performance<br />

and industry standards.<br />

However, dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes come at a cost. In particular, they can be costly<br />

for small industry groups. One opti<strong>on</strong> is for dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> to operate across<br />

different sectors with similar products/services which may reduce costs to business<br />

and reduce c<strong>on</strong>fusi<strong>on</strong> for c<strong>on</strong>sumers. Also, there may be scope to c<strong>on</strong>solidate dispute<br />

resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes.<br />

The following chapter explores some opti<strong>on</strong>s that facilitate the improvement and<br />

harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes.<br />

Principles<br />

¾ The type of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme, if required, should depend <strong>on</strong> the<br />

nature of the complaints and type of self-regulatory model.<br />

¾ A scheme is <strong>on</strong>ly as effective as its broader coverage of industry participants,<br />

so it should aim for comprehensive membership.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

41. In the future dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes may operate across different sectors<br />

with similar products/services, driven by changes in technology and market<br />

circumstances. Harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of schemes would be less costly and would also be<br />

less c<strong>on</strong>fusing to c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

42. Promoti<strong>on</strong> of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes to c<strong>on</strong>sumers raises their awareness<br />

of the availability of quick and inexpensive redress.<br />

105


Range of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes<br />

In recent years, the growth in self-regulati<strong>on</strong> has seen an expansi<strong>on</strong> in the range of<br />

redress mechanisms available to c<strong>on</strong>sumers well bey<strong>on</strong>d the traditi<strong>on</strong>al sphere of<br />

Small and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Claims Courts and their equivalents. A number of<br />

industry-based dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes provide c<strong>on</strong>sumers with a cheap and<br />

accessible means of resolving disputes.<br />

The form of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes also varies depending <strong>on</strong> the nature and<br />

quantity of complaints. Two of the biggest dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes are the<br />

<strong>Australian</strong> Banking <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman and the General Insurance Enquiries and<br />

Complaints Scheme. These schemes have a large number of staff dealing with up to<br />

50 000 inquiries per year. 312 In c<strong>on</strong>trast, the Teleph<strong>on</strong>e Informati<strong>on</strong> Services Standards<br />

Council, which handles c<strong>on</strong>sumer complaints about primarily ‘0055/1900’ teleph<strong>on</strong>e<br />

numbers, has a small number of staff and generally deals with complaints of a low<br />

m<strong>on</strong>etary value. 313<br />

As discussed in chapter 6, dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes can be expensive. A ‘Rolls<br />

Royce’ dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme is not necessary if the complaints are minor and<br />

are of small m<strong>on</strong>etary value or significance. Again, the type of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

scheme should be that which imposes the least cost of compliance c<strong>on</strong>sistent with<br />

achieving the identified objectives.<br />

As a general principle, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that the type of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

scheme that best meets c<strong>on</strong>sumer needs will depend <strong>on</strong> the nature of the complaints.<br />

However, an overarching c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> that will apply to all schemes is that a<br />

scheme is <strong>on</strong>ly as effective as its coverage of market participants, or the extent to<br />

which c<strong>on</strong>sumers can factor dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> participati<strong>on</strong> into their purchasing<br />

decisi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>vergence<br />

A challenge for self-regulatory schemes is that <strong>Australian</strong> markets are dynamic<br />

markets with increasing c<strong>on</strong>vergence and globalisati<strong>on</strong>. Clayt<strong>on</strong> Utz suggested that<br />

future codes will need to be more inter-industry rather than intra-industry and<br />

adaptable to take into account changing c<strong>on</strong>sumer relati<strong>on</strong>ships resulting from<br />

advances in technologies and adapting delivery systems. 314<br />

Hence, market forces may lead self-regulatory schemes being developed al<strong>on</strong>g more<br />

functi<strong>on</strong>al lines. For example, c<strong>on</strong>vergence of industry sectors and the rapid<br />

redrawing of industry boundaries are occurring in telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s. The Service<br />

Providers <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that the telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s industry<br />

312 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 30.<br />

313 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the Teleph<strong>on</strong>e Informati<strong>on</strong> Services Standards Council, Sydney,<br />

1 March 2000.<br />

314 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 43, p. 1.<br />

106


ings a traditi<strong>on</strong> of detailed regulati<strong>on</strong> and standardisati<strong>on</strong> and an engineering<br />

culture that insists <strong>on</strong> industrial strength, reliability and simplicity of user interfaces.<br />

The informati<strong>on</strong> technology industry sector has relied <strong>on</strong> a relative absence of<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> to support decades of rapid growth and technological change.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>vergence poses c<strong>on</strong>tinuing challenges for regulators and the self-regulatory<br />

process. The Associati<strong>on</strong> argued that there needs to be recogniti<strong>on</strong> that these basic<br />

regulatory principles will need to be directed primarily at cross-industry activities<br />

rather than industry-specific transacti<strong>on</strong>s and processes. 315<br />

Similarly, c<strong>on</strong>vergence c<strong>on</strong>tinues to occur in the finance sector, generating pressure<br />

for the merger of codes and dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes. However, the financial<br />

services industry is different to other industries in that there is a proliferati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes and there are other factors driving rati<strong>on</strong>alisati<strong>on</strong> in the<br />

industry. ASIC commented that membership of an approved scheme has become<br />

mandatory for an increasing number of industry participants, and existing<br />

complaints resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes are subject to c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> under ASIC’s Policy<br />

Statement 139. Further, ASIC commented that the Corporate Law Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Reform<br />

Program (CLERP) requirements for dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme membership are also<br />

likely to be a key driver of rati<strong>on</strong>alisati<strong>on</strong>. 316 C<strong>on</strong>vergence and the establishment of<br />

corporate composite service providers will drive fewer schemes.<br />

Potential for dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes to operate across<br />

different sectors with similar products/services<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders that it is possible for dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes to cover<br />

different sectors of industries with similar products/services <strong>on</strong> a shared cost basis<br />

as a means of capitalising <strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale. For example, the <strong>Australian</strong> Direct<br />

Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong> (ADMA) has a dispute mechanism that operates across a<br />

range of different sectors and industries. ADMA commented that their code binds all<br />

ADMA members and all employees, agents or subc<strong>on</strong>tractors of ADMA members. It<br />

requires members to ensure their suppliers comply, by requiring that this is a<br />

c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> of c<strong>on</strong>tracts between members and their suppliers. The Code seeks to curb<br />

behaviour by members that may be inc<strong>on</strong>sistent with widely accepted best practices<br />

in direct marketing. ADMA commented that this approach has been applied<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sistently across all direct marketing media and direct marketing activity <strong>on</strong> both<br />

the user and supplier sides of the ADMA membership. 317<br />

In theory, there are a number of advantages for dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes to<br />

operate across different industries and sectors with similar products/services. The<br />

main advantage is that more rati<strong>on</strong>alised schemes will benefit from lower costs<br />

overall by virtue of the ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale. These lower costs can be passed <strong>on</strong>to<br />

industry members and c<strong>on</strong>sumers. C<strong>on</strong>sumers would also benefit through a less<br />

315 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 25, p. 2.<br />

316 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 26.<br />

317 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 36, p. 4.<br />

107


c<strong>on</strong>fusing and better promoted dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> system. From a c<strong>on</strong>sumer’s<br />

perspective, a ‘<strong>on</strong>e stop shop’ with a single co-ordinated access point decreases the<br />

need for c<strong>on</strong>sumers to be referred from <strong>on</strong>e scheme to another.<br />

The Financial <strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Service suggested that schemes should be willing<br />

to cover different sectors of industry if it is of no cost to them. Cross industry<br />

schemes would be more effective so l<strong>on</strong>g as the industries have some comm<strong>on</strong><br />

thread. 318<br />

However, as discussed elsewhere, industry commitment is very important in<br />

establishing and maintaining self-regulatory schemes. 319 Sharing schemes may lead to<br />

a loss of ‘industry ownership’ and therefore commitment in some schemes. During<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s some industry bodies also commented that larger schemes<br />

would need to avoid becoming bureaucratic. 320 Clearly, harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of schemes<br />

would require some greater formality in administrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The Investment and Financial Services Associati<strong>on</strong> commented that industry<br />

schemes c<strong>on</strong>sistently benefit from expertise and industry knowledge <strong>on</strong> the part of<br />

those who establish them. The need for schemes to recruit directors, adjudicators,<br />

panel members and other pers<strong>on</strong>nel who have specialised knowledge will, in the<br />

case of very large schemes, translate to a need for bureaucratic processes and a<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequent remoteness from both industry members and c<strong>on</strong>sumers. 321<br />

Further, although the Law Council of Australia recognised that there is no reas<strong>on</strong><br />

why dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes cannot operate across different sectors of industries,<br />

the Council commented that c<strong>on</strong>sumer rights must be maintained. In particular, the<br />

Law Council of Australia argued that c<strong>on</strong>sumers (unlike industry) are not c<strong>on</strong>cerned<br />

about the cost of these schemes. Any suggesti<strong>on</strong>s of making cross industry schemes<br />

more cost-effective c<strong>on</strong>jures up staff cuts and procedure cuts. To the c<strong>on</strong>sumer, the<br />

costs of goods and services that are perhaps slightly lower in the short run is<br />

inadequate compensati<strong>on</strong> for the erosi<strong>on</strong> of the rights they currently have and the<br />

rights they should have. 322<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that in the future cross-sector dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes<br />

may be used more, driven by changes in technology and market circumstances.<br />

Harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of schemes would be less costly and c<strong>on</strong>fusing to c<strong>on</strong>sumers and the<br />

use of umbrella-type arrangements with a single co-ordinated access point would<br />

likewise be of assistance to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. However, the issue is whether specialised<br />

functi<strong>on</strong>al services can be provided by fewer schemes.<br />

318 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 15, p. 4.<br />

319 Chapter 5 indicated that industry commitment leads to more effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

320 For example, <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the Insurance Brokers’ Dispute Facility, Melbourne,<br />

22 November 1999. It commented that it would be hard to point the c<strong>on</strong>sumer in the right<br />

directi<strong>on</strong> if there was just <strong>on</strong>e broad scheme covering financial services.<br />

321 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 41, p. 4.<br />

322 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 19, p. 10.<br />

108


Shared case management/dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms<br />

Apart from the possibility of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes covering different sectors of<br />

industries with similar products/services, it may also be possible for industries to<br />

share dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes. In particular, there are opportunities for schemes<br />

to share backend services to the benefit of the respective industries. For example,<br />

Insurance, Enquiries and Complaints Limited commented that it currently performs<br />

accounting, payroll, and Company Secretary functi<strong>on</strong>s for the Financial <strong>Industry</strong><br />

Complaints Service scheme to the financial benefit of both organisati<strong>on</strong>s and their<br />

associated industries. 323<br />

ASIC commented that rati<strong>on</strong>alised schemes will benefit from lower costs overall by<br />

virtue of the ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale arising from a single budget (e.g. for administrati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

property and marketing) that would otherwise have to be generated for several<br />

schemes. These lower costs can be passed <strong>on</strong>to industry members. 324<br />

However, Insurance, Enquiries and Complaints Limited stated that careful<br />

c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> must be given to the beneficial effect that a high degree of industry<br />

‘ownership’ has had for its scheme and other schemes. 325 Also, the Law Council of<br />

Australia stated that shared case management and dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms<br />

can be viable <strong>on</strong>ly if c<strong>on</strong>sumer safeguards are maintained. 326<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>on</strong>e smaller industry associati<strong>on</strong> observed that there were no ec<strong>on</strong>omies<br />

of scale to join with other schemes. 327<br />

On balance, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> recognises that sharing services is <strong>on</strong>e means for smaller<br />

industry associati<strong>on</strong>s and smaller businesses to be involved in dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

schemes.<br />

Overall, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>siders it is important that the structure of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is<br />

flexible and does not become the site of instituti<strong>on</strong>al ‘empire building’ that will prove<br />

costly for both industry members and c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

Promoting dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes<br />

The promoti<strong>on</strong> of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes is both beneficial to industry and to the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer. For industry, a dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme can be used as a marketing tool<br />

to differentiate themselves from competitors. Whereas, for the c<strong>on</strong>sumer, the<br />

promoti<strong>on</strong> of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes informs them of their rights.<br />

323 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 8, p. 4.<br />

324 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 25.<br />

325 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 8, p. 4.<br />

326 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 19, p. 10.<br />

327 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Furnishing <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> of Australia Ltd,<br />

Melbourne, 23 November 1999.<br />

109


The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> heard that an United Kingdom industry associati<strong>on</strong> was loath to<br />

promote its dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme in fear that people might find out about it. 328<br />

While this story is extreme, it illustrates that unless a scheme is promoted then a<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer may not even know to avail themselves of a quick and inexpensive redress<br />

mechanism. Access is very important for effective self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

c<strong>on</strong>siders that the promoti<strong>on</strong> of schemes is the resp<strong>on</strong>sibility of both industry and<br />

Government, and to a lesser extent c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups and counselling services.<br />

The Law Council of Australia commented that industry can improve access by<br />

providing effective, simple communicati<strong>on</strong> which allows the c<strong>on</strong>sumer to fairly<br />

present grievances and complaints. <strong>Industry</strong> should provide informati<strong>on</strong> packages to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers when goods or services are provided. 329 For example, Insurance Enquiries<br />

and Complaints Limited stated that c<strong>on</strong>sumer access to the scheme is ensured by the<br />

Code requirement that a member company inform the c<strong>on</strong>sumer about the external<br />

dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme <strong>on</strong>ce an internal dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> decisi<strong>on</strong> has been<br />

reached. 330<br />

Similarly, the Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman (TIO) commented that<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers are aware of the Scheme’s jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> and of the limits <strong>on</strong> that<br />

jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>. Apart from general media and other activities, the Scheme provides a<br />

booklet <strong>on</strong> the TIO’s functi<strong>on</strong>s to every complainant who c<strong>on</strong>tacts the TIO. 331<br />

Further, for promoti<strong>on</strong> to be effective for c<strong>on</strong>sumers it also needs to focus <strong>on</strong> the<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>s that c<strong>on</strong>sumers go to when there is a problem , for example<br />

Fair-trading agencies or financial counsellors. There will always be insufficient<br />

resources to educate c<strong>on</strong>sumers of a service which is <strong>on</strong>ly likely to be used in a<br />

minuscule number of cases.<br />

The Government can also c<strong>on</strong>tribute to the harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

schemes. A couple of Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth initiatives are discussed below.<br />

Directory of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Schemes and Complaint<br />

Handling Organisati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

One initiative that has been useful is the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth’s Directory of C<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Schemes and Complaint Handling Organisati<strong>on</strong>s which sets out<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes, complaint handling organisati<strong>on</strong>s and other<br />

useful c<strong>on</strong>tacts such as fair-trading agencies. 332 The Directory is a practical reference<br />

328 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s in Melbourne, 22 November 1999.<br />

329 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 19, p. 10.<br />

330 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 8, p. 4.<br />

331 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 21, p. 11.<br />

332 C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Divisi<strong>on</strong>, Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Department of Treasury 2000, Directory of<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Schemes and Complaint Handling Organisati<strong>on</strong>s, 4th editi<strong>on</strong>, released<br />

by the Minister for Financial Services and Regulati<strong>on</strong>, the H<strong>on</strong> Joe Hockey MP. This document<br />

is available <strong>on</strong> the Internet at http://www.treasury.gov.au/publicati<strong>on</strong>s/pubs.asp.<br />

110


guide for individual c<strong>on</strong>sumers and organisati<strong>on</strong>s that advise c<strong>on</strong>sumers and small<br />

business.<br />

A number of industry associati<strong>on</strong>s, c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups and government agencies<br />

submitted that the Directory has been useful. For example, the Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman commented that there is more than anecdotal evidence that<br />

the Directory is an important initiative. The Directory is comm<strong>on</strong>ly used by<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups, legal aid workers and financial counsellors to ensure that<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers are directed to the appropriate redress mechanism. 333 Similarly, the<br />

Financial <strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Service commented that the Directory is ‘most<br />

helpful’ and the scheme distributes it when presenting seminars. 334<br />

Financial Complaints Referral Centre<br />

As discussed elsewhere, access to schemes is very important for self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to be<br />

effective and there is evidence to suggest that c<strong>on</strong>sumers get c<strong>on</strong>fused and frustrated<br />

if they have to go through multiple schemes. In February 1998, a Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth<br />

initiative to overcome the problem of c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fusi<strong>on</strong> associated with a<br />

proliferati<strong>on</strong> of schemes in the financial services industry was the introducti<strong>on</strong> of the<br />

Financial Complaints Referral Centre, operated by ASIC.<br />

It operated as a portal to the dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes in the financial services<br />

industry. The Centre’s staff advised callers to refer their complaints to the relevant<br />

service provider in the first instance and provided c<strong>on</strong>tact details for the appropriate<br />

dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme(s) if a deadlock remained.<br />

The operati<strong>on</strong>s of the Centre were reviewed by ASIC in late 1998 and February 1999.<br />

ASIC commented that the reviews found that around 5 to 6 calls per day were being<br />

referred to the industry-funded complaint schemes. 335 For the purpose of comparis<strong>on</strong>,<br />

the two largest industry ADR schemes — the <strong>Australian</strong> Banking <strong>Industry</strong><br />

Ombudsman and the Insurance Enquiries and Complaints — each receive between<br />

45,000 to 50,000 teleph<strong>on</strong>e c<strong>on</strong>tacts per year.<br />

The views expressed by industry and c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups during the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s also indicated that the Financial Complaints Referral Centre has not<br />

been effective in channelling calls.<br />

ASIC commented that during the Referral Centre’s development, industry<br />

stakeholders expressed reservati<strong>on</strong>s not <strong>on</strong>ly about the actual demand for a central<br />

gateway, but also that the promoti<strong>on</strong> of the Centre might detract from the efforts of<br />

333 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 21, p. 11.<br />

334 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 15, p. 5.<br />

335 Submissi<strong>on</strong> number 37, p. 30.<br />

111


the dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes to effectively promote themselves. Thus, detracting<br />

from industry’s sense of ownership of the established dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> processes. 336<br />

ASIC submitted that there was also resistance from existing dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

schemes to devoting significant resources to the establishment and operati<strong>on</strong> of a<br />

central gateway without detailed evidence that there was a sufficient level of<br />

demand for the service. 337<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> notes that the Referral Centre has now been closed. The referral of<br />

complainants to those dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes dealing with general and life<br />

insurance, superannuati<strong>on</strong> and banking is a role that ASIC’s Infoline would have<br />

played in any event, and that it will c<strong>on</strong>tinue to play in the future. 338<br />

The <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> understands the schemes themselves already have established referral<br />

mechanisms to assist c<strong>on</strong>sumers to locate the most appropriate dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

mechanism.<br />

336 Ibid.<br />

337 Ibid.<br />

338 ASIC Infoline number is 1300 300 630.<br />

112


Appendix A<br />

List of submissi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

1. Motor Trades Associati<strong>on</strong> of Australia<br />

2. Micro Business Network Pty Ltd<br />

3. Nati<strong>on</strong>al Insurance Brokers Associati<strong>on</strong> of Australia<br />

4. Red Tape Reducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> [Queensland]<br />

5. Roger Clarke, Xamax C<strong>on</strong>sultancy Pty Ltd<br />

6. Cable &Wireless Optus Limited<br />

7. NRMA Limited<br />

8. Insurance Enquiries & Complaints Limited<br />

9. PowerTel Limited<br />

10. <strong>Australian</strong> Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Associati<strong>on</strong> Inc<br />

11. <strong>Australian</strong> Supermarket Institute<br />

12. <strong>Australian</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> of Nati<strong>on</strong>al Advertisers<br />

13. Standards Australia<br />

14. Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Advisory Council<br />

15. Financial <strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Service Limited<br />

16. <strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

17. <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s Authority<br />

18. Insurance Council of Australia Limited<br />

19. Law Council of Australia (C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Committee of the General Practice<br />

Secti<strong>on</strong>)<br />

20. Small Enterprise Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Centre Limited<br />

113


21. Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman<br />

22. Associati<strong>on</strong> of Superannuati<strong>on</strong> Funds of Australia Limited<br />

23. <strong>Australian</strong> Toy Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

24. Legal Aid New South Wales<br />

25. Service Providers <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> Inc<br />

26. The Instituti<strong>on</strong> of Engineers, Australia<br />

27. <strong>Australian</strong> Chamber of Commerce and <strong>Industry</strong><br />

28. Department of Agriculture, Fisheries and Forestry<br />

29. Joint submissi<strong>on</strong> from: C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre Victoria, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit Legal<br />

Service (Vic) and the Financial and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Rights Council (Vic)<br />

30. The <strong>Australian</strong> Food and Grocery Council<br />

31. Department of <strong>Industry</strong>, Science and Resources<br />

32. C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Network<br />

33. <strong>Australian</strong> Society of Certified Practising Accountants & The Institute of<br />

Chartered Accountants in Australia<br />

34. Federati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Australian</strong> Commercial Televisi<strong>on</strong> Stati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

35. Federati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Australian</strong> Radio Broadcasters<br />

36. <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

37. <strong>Australian</strong> Securities and Investments Commissi<strong>on</strong><br />

38. Office of Small Business, Department of Employment, Workplace Relati<strong>on</strong>s and<br />

Small Business<br />

39. <strong>Australian</strong> Subscripti<strong>on</strong> Televisi<strong>on</strong> and Radio Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

40. The Royal Aer<strong>on</strong>autical Society<br />

41. Investment and Financial Services Associati<strong>on</strong> Limited<br />

42. <strong>Australian</strong> Competiti<strong>on</strong> and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Commissi<strong>on</strong><br />

43. Clayt<strong>on</strong> Utz<br />

44. Department of Health and Aged Care<br />

114


Appendix B:<br />

List of parties c<strong>on</strong>sulted<br />

1. Associati<strong>on</strong> of Superannuati<strong>on</strong> Funds of Australia<br />

2. <strong>Australian</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> of Nati<strong>on</strong>al Advertisers<br />

3. <strong>Australian</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> of Permanent Building Societies<br />

4. <strong>Australian</strong> Bankers’ Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

5. <strong>Australian</strong> Banking <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman<br />

6. <strong>Australian</strong> Broadcasting Authority<br />

7. <strong>Australian</strong> Business Ltd<br />

8. <strong>Australian</strong> Chamber of Commerce and <strong>Industry</strong><br />

9. <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s Authority<br />

10. <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Forum<br />

11. <strong>Australian</strong> Competiti<strong>on</strong> and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Commissi<strong>on</strong><br />

12. <strong>Australian</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

13. <strong>Australian</strong> Direct Marketing Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

14. <strong>Australian</strong> Electrical and Electr<strong>on</strong>ics Manufacturers’ Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

15. <strong>Australian</strong> Financial Counselling and Credit Reform Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

16. <strong>Australian</strong> Food and Grocery Council<br />

17. <strong>Australian</strong> Informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

18. <strong>Australian</strong> Institute of Company Directors<br />

19. <strong>Australian</strong> Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

20. <strong>Australian</strong> Press Council<br />

115


21. <strong>Australian</strong> Private Hospitals Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

22. <strong>Australian</strong> Securities and Investments Commissi<strong>on</strong><br />

23. <strong>Australian</strong> Subscripti<strong>on</strong> Televisi<strong>on</strong> and Radio Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

24. <strong>Australian</strong> Supermarket Institute<br />

25. <strong>Australian</strong> Toy Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

26. Business and Professi<strong>on</strong>al Women of Australia<br />

27. Business Council of Australia<br />

28. C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Centre Victoria<br />

29. C<strong>on</strong>sumer Law Committee of the Law Council of Australia<br />

30. C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Network<br />

31. Cott<strong>on</strong> Australia<br />

32. Council of Small Business Organisati<strong>on</strong>s of Australia<br />

33. Credit Uni<strong>on</strong> Dispute Reference Centre<br />

34. Credit Uni<strong>on</strong> Services Corporati<strong>on</strong> of Australia Limited<br />

35. Department of Communicati<strong>on</strong>s, Informati<strong>on</strong> Technology and the Arts<br />

36. Department of Health and Aged Care<br />

37. Department of Immigrati<strong>on</strong> and Multicultural Affairs<br />

38. Department of <strong>Industry</strong>, Science and Resources<br />

39. Federal Privacy Commissi<strong>on</strong>er<br />

40. Federati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Australian</strong> Commercial Televisi<strong>on</strong> Stati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

41. Federati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Australian</strong> Radio Broadcasters<br />

42. Financial <strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Service Ltd<br />

43. Financial Services Complaints Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Scheme (now merged with Financial<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> Complaints Service Ltd)<br />

44. Financial Services C<strong>on</strong>sumer Policy Centre<br />

45. Fund Raising Institute of Australia<br />

116


46. General Insurance Enquiries and Complaints Scheme<br />

47. Housing <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

48. Insurance Brokers Dispute Facility<br />

49. Insurance Council of Australia<br />

50. Internet <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

51. Investment and Financial Services Associati<strong>on</strong><br />

52. Jewellers Associati<strong>on</strong> of Australia<br />

53. Nati<strong>on</strong>al Furnishing <strong>Industry</strong> Associati<strong>on</strong> of Australia<br />

54. NSW C<strong>on</strong>sumer Credit Legal Centre<br />

55. Office of Regulati<strong>on</strong> Review<br />

56. Office of Small Business, Department of Employment, Workplace Relati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

and Small Business<br />

57. Property Council of Australia<br />

58. Proprietary Medicines Associati<strong>on</strong> of Australia<br />

59. Real Estate Institute of Australia<br />

60. Society of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Professi<strong>on</strong>als in Business<br />

61. Standards Australia<br />

62. Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman<br />

63. Teleph<strong>on</strong>e Informati<strong>on</strong> Services Standards Council<br />

117


Appendix C<br />

Regulatory framework for<br />

industry codes in Australia<br />

In undertaking its inquiry, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> will … have regard to the changing<br />

regulatory envir<strong>on</strong>ment and, in particular, developments in industry self-regulatory<br />

practice in other jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s within Australia…<br />

This purpose of this paper is to outline recent developments in Australia, at the<br />

Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth level and also at the State and Territory level, whereby industry<br />

self-regulatory schemes have been incorporated into regulatory frameworks.<br />

Over the last decade, the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth has established regulatory regimes for<br />

broadcasting and telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s that incorporate industry codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct.<br />

The Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth is presently in the process of developing and implementing<br />

regulatory regimes in the financial services sector and privacy standards for pers<strong>on</strong>al<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> handling in the private sector. Both regimes allow for the development<br />

of industry codes and complaint handling schemes.<br />

At the same time, most <strong>Australian</strong> jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s, including the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth have<br />

recognised that there will be situati<strong>on</strong>s where industry self-regulatory schemes may<br />

need to be underpinned in legislati<strong>on</strong> to make such schemes work effectively.<br />

The Fair-Trading amendments to the Trade Practices Act 1974 [Cth], which took effect<br />

in 1998, provide a general power to make industry codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct enforceable at<br />

law. Importantly, this regulatory opti<strong>on</strong> also gives the <strong>Australian</strong> Competiti<strong>on</strong> and<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Commissi<strong>on</strong> (ACCC) an enforcement role ensuring that industry<br />

participants comply with code provisi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

States and Territories have also embraced the regulatory opti<strong>on</strong> of mandatory codes<br />

in their respective Fair Trading Acts.<br />

This paper will start by looking at the overarching regulatory framework for<br />

underpinning industry codes in the Trade Practices Act, and equivalent State and<br />

Territory provisi<strong>on</strong>s, then moves <strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>sider specific regulatory frameworks for<br />

industry codes in particular sectors — namely broadcasting, telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

financial services, the health sector and privacy.<br />

In examining these regulatory frameworks, the emphasis is not just <strong>on</strong> the policy for<br />

mandatory codes but also <strong>on</strong> how they actually operate. This involves looking at<br />

119


how codes are developed and approved, how complaints are handled and sancti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

imposed for n<strong>on</strong>-compliance, and how codes are m<strong>on</strong>itored and reviewed.<br />

It is important to remember that many of these regulatory frameworks are relatively<br />

new. For example, the regulatory opti<strong>on</strong> of underpinning codes in the Trade<br />

Practices Act has <strong>on</strong>ly been activated for <strong>on</strong>e industry code to date — the Franchising<br />

Code of Practice. N<strong>on</strong>etheless, developments in this area form part of the c<strong>on</strong>text for<br />

the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> inquiry.<br />

Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth framework for codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct 339<br />

Part IVB of the Trade Practices Act 1974 provides for industry codes to be<br />

underpinned in the Act. Secti<strong>on</strong> 51AD gives legislative backing to prescribed<br />

industry codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct and provides for the <strong>Australian</strong> Competiti<strong>on</strong> and<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Commissi<strong>on</strong> (ACCC) to take acti<strong>on</strong> against breaches of prescribed codes.<br />

Secti<strong>on</strong> 51AE provides for industry codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct to be prescribed in regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

proposed by the resp<strong>on</strong>sible Minister.<br />

Regulati<strong>on</strong>s may declare a code to be mandatory or voluntary. Mandatory codes are<br />

binding <strong>on</strong> all industry participants. Voluntary prescribed codes are <strong>on</strong>ly binding <strong>on</strong><br />

those members of an industry or professi<strong>on</strong> who have formally subscribed to the<br />

code. Prescribed voluntary codes could, for example, apply to <strong>on</strong>ly members of the<br />

industry associati<strong>on</strong> administering the code. The ACCC keeps a public register of<br />

companies bound by voluntary codes.<br />

The criteria used to c<strong>on</strong>sider if a code should be prescribed<br />

The Minister will <strong>on</strong>ly c<strong>on</strong>sider initiating a proposal for prescripti<strong>on</strong> of a code of<br />

c<strong>on</strong>duct if:<br />

¾ The code would remedy an identified market failure or promote a social policy<br />

objective; and<br />

¾ The code would be the most effective means for remedying that market failure<br />

or promoting that policy objective; and<br />

¾ The benefits of the code to the community as a whole would outweigh any<br />

costs; and<br />

¾ There are significant and irremediable deficiencies in any existing<br />

self-regulatory regime — for example, the code scheme has inadequate industry<br />

coverage or the code itself fails to address industry problems; and<br />

339 Informati<strong>on</strong> taken from: Department of the Treasury 1999, Prescribed codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct — policy<br />

guidelines <strong>on</strong> making industry codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct enforceable under the Trade Practices Act 1974.<br />

120


¾ A systemic enforcement issue exists because there is a history of breaches of any<br />

voluntary industry codes; and<br />

¾ A range of self-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>s and ‘light-handed’ quasi-regulatory opti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

has been examined and dem<strong>on</strong>strated to be ineffective.<br />

There is also a need to c<strong>on</strong>sider whether a matter is appropriate for enforcement<br />

under the Trade Practices Act and whether there is a need for nati<strong>on</strong>al applicati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

an enforceable code.<br />

At present, Regulati<strong>on</strong> Impact Statements (RIS’s) are required in respect of new<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> that is likely to impose compliance costs <strong>on</strong> businesses. The Office of<br />

Regulati<strong>on</strong> Review has published A Guide to Regulati<strong>on</strong>, setting out the procedure<br />

for the preparati<strong>on</strong> of RIS’s. This document is available <strong>on</strong> the Internet at:<br />

http://www.pc.gov.au/orr/reguide2/index.html.<br />

Preparati<strong>on</strong> of a code<br />

Formal proposals for prescripti<strong>on</strong> of codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct are initiated at the<br />

Government level, following representati<strong>on</strong>s from industry participants, c<strong>on</strong>sumers<br />

or government authorities about problems in a particular industry.<br />

If codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct are to be underpinned in the Trade Practices Act then the<br />

enforceable provisi<strong>on</strong>s must be drafted in clear, unambiguous language that can be<br />

clearly interpreted by industry participants, c<strong>on</strong>sumers, investigators and the courts.<br />

The Office of Legislative <strong>Draft</strong>ing will be brought into c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> processes at an<br />

early stage and will be resp<strong>on</strong>sible for drafting the final versi<strong>on</strong> of the code.<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> codes are expected to follow the Government’s policy guidelines <strong>on</strong><br />

developing effective codes and dispute schemes. 340<br />

The process that will be followed when codes are prescribed under the Trade<br />

Practices Act is outlined briefly below:<br />

Stage 1 — early notificati<strong>on</strong><br />

Key stakeholders will be notified if a Minister is c<strong>on</strong>sidering proposing prescripti<strong>on</strong><br />

of an industry code.<br />

340 The ‘Codes Kit’ gives policy guidance and advice <strong>on</strong> developing industry based codes of<br />

c<strong>on</strong>duct. The Kit includes: Codes of C<strong>on</strong>duct: Policy Framework; Prescribed Codes of C<strong>on</strong>duct —<br />

Policy guidelines <strong>on</strong> making industry codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct enforceable under the Trade Practices Act 1974;<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Redress Study — A study of c<strong>on</strong>sumer redress models and recommendati<strong>on</strong>s for acti<strong>on</strong>; and<br />

Benchmarks for <strong>Industry</strong>-Based Customer Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> Schemes.<br />

Copies of the Kit are available from the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Divisi<strong>on</strong> of the Treasury and the<br />

publicati<strong>on</strong>s can also be located <strong>on</strong> the Internet at: http://www.treasury.gov.au.<br />

121


Stage 2 — draft regulati<strong>on</strong> impact statement<br />

The Department with policy carriage of the code will prepare a draft Regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

Impact Statement.<br />

Stage 3 — wide c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong><br />

There will follow a comprehensive program of c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with businesses,<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers and relevant government agencies, providing all stakeholders with an<br />

opportunity to make written submissi<strong>on</strong>s and to attend any roundtable c<strong>on</strong>ferences<br />

held.<br />

Stage 4 — final regulati<strong>on</strong> impact statement<br />

At the c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> of the c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with industry, the draft Regulati<strong>on</strong> Impact<br />

Statement will be revised in the light of informati<strong>on</strong> and views put forward in the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> process, as will the code itself. The final assessment will be submitted to<br />

the Office of Regulati<strong>on</strong> Review for approval. Any shortcomings in the analysis<br />

identified at this stage will be remedied.<br />

Stage 5 — making regulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

The Code, together with the Regulati<strong>on</strong> Impact Statement, will be submitted to the<br />

Executive Council for approval. If the Executive Council approves prescripti<strong>on</strong> of the<br />

code, the Governor-General will be asked to make regulati<strong>on</strong>s to this effect.<br />

The regulati<strong>on</strong>s will be gazetted and then normal parliamentary procedures will be<br />

followed.<br />

Enforcement<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> bodies formulating codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct are encouraged to establish low cost<br />

dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms. However, the dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms<br />

themselves will not necessarily be appropriate for prescripti<strong>on</strong> under the Trade<br />

Practices Act.<br />

For c<strong>on</strong>sumers and small business customers, the principal benefit of a prescribed<br />

code is that commitments under a code are enforceable by the ACCC or by private<br />

acti<strong>on</strong> under the Trade Practices Act, with a wide range of remedies. A court may<br />

impose remedies including:<br />

¾ damages to c<strong>on</strong>sumers or business customers who have been hurt;<br />

¾ injuncti<strong>on</strong>s to restrain companies from engaging in c<strong>on</strong>duct in breach of a code;<br />

¾ court orders requiring corrective advertising or the disclosure of informati<strong>on</strong>;<br />

¾ court orders declaring a c<strong>on</strong>tract to be void or varying the terms of a c<strong>on</strong>tract;<br />

and/or<br />

¾ court orders requiring m<strong>on</strong>ey to be refunded.<br />

122


Companies are not required to pay fines for a breach of secti<strong>on</strong> 51AD.<br />

State and Territory framework for codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct<br />

All States and Territories in Australia have legislative provisi<strong>on</strong>s supporting codes of<br />

c<strong>on</strong>duct. 341<br />

The legislati<strong>on</strong> in New South Wales, Queensland, Western Australia, Tasmania, the<br />

Northern Territory and the ACT, provides a framework for provisi<strong>on</strong>s between a<br />

particular class of suppliers and c<strong>on</strong>sumers as well as a particular class of pers<strong>on</strong>s in<br />

relati<strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>sumers.<br />

Generally, after c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with relevant industry and c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups, draft<br />

codes are put to the resp<strong>on</strong>sible minister for approval. If approved, the code of<br />

practice can then be prescribed. In Tasmania, a code of practice must be endorsed by<br />

a resoluti<strong>on</strong> of both Houses of Parliament before it can be prescribed. The Governor<br />

in South Australia has the power to make regulati<strong>on</strong>s that may prescribe codes of<br />

practice.<br />

The complaints process and enforcement<br />

Many state and territory codes encourage internal dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> before relying<br />

<strong>on</strong> provisi<strong>on</strong>s set in legislati<strong>on</strong>. As a general guide, legislative enforcement in a<br />

number of jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s is as follows. If a code is breached, a pers<strong>on</strong> may be<br />

requested by the Director (for C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs) or another government<br />

representative to comply with an undertaking to remedy the c<strong>on</strong>traventi<strong>on</strong>. If a<br />

pers<strong>on</strong> fails to comply with a request of the Director to give an undertaking, a<br />

judicial or quasi-judicial body (such as a tribunal or local court) may, <strong>on</strong> applicati<strong>on</strong><br />

of the Director and <strong>on</strong> being satisfied there were sufficient grounds, order a pers<strong>on</strong> to<br />

act in a manner to or to refrain from acting in a manner as set out in the undertaking.<br />

In some cases c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s and other matters may also be dealt with in the order.<br />

Examples of codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct underpinned by State and Territory fair trading<br />

legislati<strong>on</strong> include:<br />

¾ The Motor Vehicle Service and Repair <strong>Industry</strong> Code of Practice, underpinned by the<br />

Fair Trading Act 1992 (ACT); and<br />

341 Fair Trading Acts:<br />

ACT Fair Trading Act 1992, Part III;<br />

NSW Fair Trading Act 1987 Part 7;<br />

Qld Fair Trading Act 1989 Secti<strong>on</strong> 88A;<br />

SA Fair Trading Act 1987 Paragraph 8(1)(f);<br />

Tas Fair Trading Act 1990 Part 4;<br />

WA Fair Trading Act 1987 Part IV;<br />

Vic Fair Trading Act 1999 Part 6;<br />

NT C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs and Fair Trading Act 1990 Part XII.<br />

123


¾ The Code of Fair Practice for Retirement Villages 1998, underpinned by the Fair<br />

Trading Act 1987 (WA).<br />

Examples of industry codes supported by legislati<strong>on</strong><br />

Broadcasting sector 342<br />

The Broadcasting Services Act 1992 allows the various broadcasting industry sectors to<br />

set their own programming guidelines in the form of codes of practice.<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Broadcasting Authority (ABA) has registered codes of practice for all<br />

broadcasting sectors, with the excepti<strong>on</strong> of the ABC and SBS who have codes that are<br />

notified to the ABA. Secti<strong>on</strong> 123A of the Broadcasting Services Act requires periodic<br />

review of the codes. The ABA m<strong>on</strong>itors complaints made to the broadcasters to<br />

assess whether the codes of practice are in accordance with prevailing community<br />

standards and c<strong>on</strong>cerns.<br />

Registrati<strong>on</strong> of codes of practice<br />

Once an industry code of practice has been developed, it is presented to the ABA for<br />

registrati<strong>on</strong>. In assessing a code of practice for registrati<strong>on</strong> the ABA c<strong>on</strong>siders three<br />

mandatory criteria. The ABA must register a code of practice if it is satisfied that:<br />

¾ the code of practice provides appropriate community safeguards for the matters<br />

covered by the code;<br />

¾ the code has been endorsed by a majority of the providers of broadcasting<br />

services in that secti<strong>on</strong> of the industry; and<br />

¾ members of the public have been given an adequate opportunity to comment<br />

<strong>on</strong> the code.<br />

Currently there are codes in the following areas: commercial televisi<strong>on</strong>, commercial<br />

radio, community broadcasting, open narrowcasting, subscripti<strong>on</strong> (pay) and the ABC<br />

and SBS.<br />

These codes can be found at:<br />

http://www.aba.gov.au/what/program/codes/index.htm<br />

The complaints process and enforcement<br />

It is open for a pers<strong>on</strong> to lodge a complaint with the ABA directly in the first<br />

instance. However, the general procedure for complaint-handling is that pers<strong>on</strong>s<br />

should approach the broadcaster first, who in turn is obliged to resp<strong>on</strong>d. However, if<br />

342 Informati<strong>on</strong> taken from http://www.aba.gov.au.<br />

124


a complainant does not receive a resp<strong>on</strong>se within 60 days, or c<strong>on</strong>siders the resp<strong>on</strong>se<br />

received to be inadequate, the matter can be referred to the ABA for investigati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The ABA refers to these as unresolved complaints and must investigate complaints<br />

so made.<br />

The ABA may make a finding that a broadcaster has breached a code of practice or a<br />

broadcaster may admit a breach of a code. Breaches of the codes are not breaches of<br />

the Act, although the ABA may make compliance with a code a c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> of licence.<br />

Generally, the ABA seeks to ensure that broadcasters take acti<strong>on</strong> to remedy breaches<br />

or to put in place procedures to ensure they are not repeated.<br />

If the ABA imposes a c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> a broadcaster’s licence and the broadcaster<br />

breaches that c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>, the broadcaster then risks penalties under the Broadcasting<br />

Act.<br />

More informati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerning codes in the broadcasting sector can be found at:<br />

http://www.aba.gov.au/what/program/codes/index.htm<br />

Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s sector 343<br />

Part 6 of the Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Act 1997 outlines how industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is to<br />

be achieved through industry initiated and developed codes of practice in the<br />

telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s sector.<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> codes can be developed by industry bodies and associati<strong>on</strong>s that represent<br />

secti<strong>on</strong>s of the telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s industry, <strong>on</strong> any matter which relates to a<br />

telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s activity, which is defined very widely in secti<strong>on</strong> 109 of the<br />

Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Act.<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> bodies can present codes to the <strong>Australian</strong> Communicati<strong>on</strong>s Authority<br />

(ACA) for registrati<strong>on</strong>. Where the ACA is satisfied that the code meets stipulated<br />

criteria it is obliged to include the code <strong>on</strong> a Register of <strong>Industry</strong> Codes and <strong>Industry</strong><br />

Standards. The criteria includes matters such as:<br />

¾ if the ACA is satisfied that the body proposing the code represents a particular<br />

secti<strong>on</strong> of the telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s industry;<br />

¾ if the code provides for appropriate community safeguards;<br />

¾ if the matters covered in the code are appropriate;<br />

¾ that groups in the industry, c<strong>on</strong>sumer bodies, the ACCC, the<br />

Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman and the Privacy Commissi<strong>on</strong>er<br />

have been c<strong>on</strong>sulted; and<br />

343 Informati<strong>on</strong> taken from http://www.aca.gov.au.<br />

125


¾ whether the code addresses public interest c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s in a way that does<br />

not impose undue financial and administrative burdens <strong>on</strong> participants in<br />

secti<strong>on</strong>s of the telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s industry.<br />

Where the ACA c<strong>on</strong>siders a code to be necessary or c<strong>on</strong>venient to provide<br />

appropriate community safeguards or otherwise deal with the performance or<br />

c<strong>on</strong>duct of the telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s industry, it may request that a representative<br />

industry body develop <strong>on</strong>e and present it to the ACA for registrati<strong>on</strong>. In the event<br />

that the code is not developed, or does not meet the registrati<strong>on</strong> criteria, the ACA<br />

may develop an industry standard. Compliance with standards is mandatory.<br />

‘Developing Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Codes for Registrati<strong>on</strong> — A Guide’ is the ACA’s<br />

accepted approach to developing and registering telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s industry<br />

codes. The Guide addresses matters such as regulatory principles such as<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>, drafting principles and administrati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The Guide can be found at:<br />

http://www.aca.gov.au/codes/codes.pdf<br />

The complaints process and enforcement<br />

Any pers<strong>on</strong> may make a complaint c<strong>on</strong>cerning a c<strong>on</strong>traventi<strong>on</strong> of the regulati<strong>on</strong> or a<br />

registered code. The ACA may investigate the complaint or if appropriate, refer the<br />

complaint to the ACCC, the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Ombudsman, the Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> Ombudsman or a complaint-handling body under the relevant code.<br />

Under normal circumstances compliance by industry participants with a registered<br />

code is voluntary. However, the ACA has powers under secti<strong>on</strong>s 121 and 122 to<br />

ensure compliance with registered codes. These powers enable the ACA to issue<br />

formal warnings to industry participants regarding breaches of the code and also to<br />

direct industry participants to comply with the provisi<strong>on</strong>s of a code where the code<br />

has been, or is being, c<strong>on</strong>travened.<br />

ACA warnings and directi<strong>on</strong>s to comply with a registered code can be issued to any<br />

participant in a secti<strong>on</strong> of the industry which is c<strong>on</strong>travening the code, whether or<br />

not that participant has voluntarily agreed to comply with the registered code, is a<br />

member of the industry body which has developed the code, or is a signatory to the<br />

code. A breach of an ACA directi<strong>on</strong> to comply may attract civil penalty provisi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Further informati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerning codes in the telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s sector can be found<br />

at:<br />

http://www.aca.gov.au/codes/index.htm<br />

126


Health sector 344<br />

The Therapeutic Goods Administrati<strong>on</strong> oversees the operati<strong>on</strong> of manufacturing<br />

practice for therapeutic goods and the advertising of therapeutic goods. The<br />

Therapeutic Goods Act 1989 (the TG Act) allows codes to be developed.<br />

For example, Good Manufacturing Practice Codes (GMP Codes) are used as a set of<br />

principles and procedures which, when followed by manufacturers of therapeutic<br />

goods, helps ensure that the products manufactured will have the required quality.<br />

The Codes are developed with industry.<br />

Enforcement of codes<br />

In Australia the TG Act requires <strong>Australian</strong> manufacturers of therapeutic goods for<br />

human use to hold a licence. It is an offence, carrying heavy penalties, to<br />

manufacture therapeutic goods without such a licence unless the goods are<br />

exempted from this requirement.<br />

Licence holders are required to comply with the Manufacturing Principles of the TG<br />

Act. These Manufacturing Principles require compliance with various GMP codes for<br />

goods such as medicinal products and sunscreens, or matters such as quality systems<br />

for medical devices. The Therapeutic Goods Administrati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>duct periodic audits<br />

of licensees to ensure that they comply with the codes. If there are issues of<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-compliance the company is informed and requested to remedy the breach. If the<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-compliance is significant or not remedied in the specified time frame there is an<br />

internal review of the n<strong>on</strong>-compliance. The internal review may recommend a<br />

revocati<strong>on</strong> of a licence if the n<strong>on</strong>-compliance is significant or c<strong>on</strong>tinuing.<br />

An example of a recently reviewed health code is the Therapeutic Goods Advertising<br />

Code. The reviewed Code was launched earlier this year. The Code addresses<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer need for a more timely, evidence-based assessment of claims made by<br />

companies marketing therapeutic products. <strong>Industry</strong>, government and c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

groups from across Australia and New Zealand were c<strong>on</strong>sulted as part of the review<br />

process.<br />

Financial sector 345 (approval of external complaints resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes)<br />

The <strong>Australian</strong> Securities and Investments Commissi<strong>on</strong> (ASIC) m<strong>on</strong>itors and<br />

promotes market integrity and c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> in the <strong>Australian</strong> financial<br />

system. C<strong>on</strong>sequently, ASIC is resp<strong>on</strong>sible for overseeing the effective operati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

external complaints resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes, and approving these schemes operating in<br />

the financial sector. To gain a licence under the Corporati<strong>on</strong>s regulati<strong>on</strong>s (for<br />

example if a pers<strong>on</strong> wished to c<strong>on</strong>duct dealing and security advising work), it is<br />

344 Informati<strong>on</strong> taken from http://www.health.gov.au.<br />

345 Informati<strong>on</strong> taken from http://www.cpd.com.au/asic/ps/ps139.pdf.<br />

127


necessary for the licensee to have an approved external resoluti<strong>on</strong> complaints scheme<br />

in place. Policy Statement 139 gives guidance <strong>on</strong> how the Commissi<strong>on</strong> will approve<br />

external complaints resoluti<strong>on</strong> schemes operating in the financial system. The policy<br />

guidelines set out requirements for any complaints scheme. Some examples of the<br />

requirements are listed below:<br />

¾ independence of the scheme;<br />

¾ an overseeing body with resp<strong>on</strong>sibility to oversee the operati<strong>on</strong>s of the scheme,<br />

to preserve the independence of the scheme and of the dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

processes;<br />

¾ sufficient coverage of the scheme;<br />

¾ promoti<strong>on</strong> of free of charge services to any complainant within the scheme’s<br />

jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>;<br />

¾ written reas<strong>on</strong>s for any decisi<strong>on</strong> made about the merits of a complaint;<br />

¾ internal procedures for dealing with n<strong>on</strong>-compliance with decisi<strong>on</strong>s;<br />

¾ when issues should be reported to the ASIC (systemic, persistent or deliberate<br />

c<strong>on</strong>duct); and<br />

¾ available remedies.<br />

The Policy Statement can be found <strong>on</strong> the Internet at:<br />

http://www.cpd.com.au/asic/ps/ps139.pdf<br />

The complaints process and enforcement<br />

In the first instance the complainant would normally make a complaint to the<br />

licensee or the internal dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> process. If there was no resoluti<strong>on</strong>, the<br />

complainant may then lodge the complaint with the external complaints resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

scheme. The complainant may also lodge the complaint with ASIC. ASIC may then<br />

investigate the complaint. In some circumstances breach of an approved complaints<br />

resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme may attract penalties under the relevant provisi<strong>on</strong>s of the<br />

Corporati<strong>on</strong>s Act and regulati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Other review mechanisms<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong> to the enforcement procedures in various pieces of the legislati<strong>on</strong>, review<br />

of decisi<strong>on</strong>s may also be available under Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth, State and Territory<br />

Administrative Appeals Tribunal systems. Ombudsman offices and complaint<br />

resoluti<strong>on</strong> bodies in Australia may also investigate certain matters.<br />

128


Informati<strong>on</strong> Privacy Protecti<strong>on</strong> 346<br />

A privacy scheme for the private sector<br />

The Privacy Amendment (Private Sector) Bill 2000 is currently before Parliament. The<br />

Bill will have important c<strong>on</strong>sequences for the way in which many private sector<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>s handle pers<strong>on</strong>al informati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Many private sector organisati<strong>on</strong>s such as bodies corporate, unincorporated<br />

associati<strong>on</strong>s, partnerships, trusts and individuals will be bound by the proposed<br />

legislati<strong>on</strong>. 347<br />

The regulatory approach adopted has been described as ‘light touch’ and encourages<br />

businesses to establish privacy codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct — with industry complaint handling<br />

mechanisms — to meet the requirements of the legislati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Privacy codes must be based <strong>on</strong> the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Privacy Principles that are set out in a<br />

Schedule to the Bill. A short summary of the effect of the Principles follows:<br />

Principle 1 — collecti<strong>on</strong><br />

An organisati<strong>on</strong> must not collect pers<strong>on</strong>al informati<strong>on</strong> unless the informati<strong>on</strong> is<br />

necessary for <strong>on</strong>e or more of its functi<strong>on</strong>s or activities. The collecting organisati<strong>on</strong><br />

must take reas<strong>on</strong>able steps to ensure the individual is aware of details such as the<br />

identity of the organisati<strong>on</strong> and how to c<strong>on</strong>tact it, why the informati<strong>on</strong> was collected<br />

and to whom the organisati<strong>on</strong> usually discloses the informati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Principle 2 — use and disclosure<br />

An organisati<strong>on</strong> must not use or disclose pers<strong>on</strong>al informati<strong>on</strong> about an individual<br />

for a purpose other than the primary purpose of collecti<strong>on</strong> unless such use or<br />

disclosure is permitted by <strong>on</strong>e of the excepti<strong>on</strong>s to Nati<strong>on</strong>al Privacy Principle 2.<br />

Principle 3 — data quality<br />

An organisati<strong>on</strong> must take reas<strong>on</strong>able steps to make sure that the pers<strong>on</strong>al<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> it collects, uses or discloses is accurate, complete and up-to-date.<br />

Principle 4 — data security<br />

An organisati<strong>on</strong> must take reas<strong>on</strong>able steps to protect the pers<strong>on</strong>al informati<strong>on</strong> it<br />

holds from misuse and loss and from unauthorised access, modificati<strong>on</strong> or<br />

disclosure. An organisati<strong>on</strong> must also take reas<strong>on</strong>able steps to destroy or<br />

permanently de-identify pers<strong>on</strong>al informati<strong>on</strong> if it is no l<strong>on</strong>ger needed for any<br />

346 Informati<strong>on</strong> taken from http://www.law.gov.au/privacy and<br />

http://www.aph.gov.au/legis.htm.<br />

347<br />

The Bill c<strong>on</strong>tains exempti<strong>on</strong>s for some organisati<strong>on</strong>s. For example, it will not apply to all small<br />

business organsiati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

129


purpose for which the informati<strong>on</strong> may be used or disclosed under Nati<strong>on</strong>al Privacy<br />

Principle 2.<br />

Principle 5 — openness<br />

An organisati<strong>on</strong> must set out in a document clearly expressed policies <strong>on</strong> its<br />

management of pers<strong>on</strong>al informati<strong>on</strong>. The organisati<strong>on</strong> must make the document<br />

available to any<strong>on</strong>e who asks for it.<br />

On request by a pers<strong>on</strong>, an organisati<strong>on</strong> must take reas<strong>on</strong>able steps to let the pers<strong>on</strong><br />

know generally, what sort of pers<strong>on</strong>al informati<strong>on</strong> it holds, for what purposes, and<br />

how it collects holds, uses and discloses that informati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Principle 6 — access and correcti<strong>on</strong><br />

If an organisati<strong>on</strong> holds pers<strong>on</strong>al informati<strong>on</strong> about an individual, it must provide<br />

the individual with access to the informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> request by the individual, unless a<br />

relevant exempti<strong>on</strong> under Nati<strong>on</strong>al Privacy Principle 6 applies.<br />

Principle 7 — identifiers<br />

An organisati<strong>on</strong> must not adopt as its own identifier of an individual an identifier of<br />

the individual that has been assigned by a Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Government agency, an<br />

agent of an agency acting in its capacity as agent, or a c<strong>on</strong>tracted service provider for<br />

a Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth c<strong>on</strong>tract acting in its capacity as a c<strong>on</strong>tracted service provider for<br />

that c<strong>on</strong>tract.<br />

An organisati<strong>on</strong> must not use or disclose an identifier assigned to an individual by<br />

an agency, or by an agent or c<strong>on</strong>tracted service provider, except in certain<br />

circumstances described in Nati<strong>on</strong>al Privacy Principle 7.<br />

Principle 8 — an<strong>on</strong>ymity<br />

Wherever it is lawful and practicable, individuals must have the opti<strong>on</strong> of not<br />

identifying themselves when entering transacti<strong>on</strong>s with an organisati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Principle 9 — transborder data flows<br />

An organisati<strong>on</strong> in Australia may transfer pers<strong>on</strong>al informati<strong>on</strong> about an individual<br />

to some<strong>on</strong>e (other than the organisati<strong>on</strong> or the individual) who is in a foreign<br />

country <strong>on</strong>ly if the requirements described in Nati<strong>on</strong>al Privacy Principle 9 are met.<br />

Principle 10 — sensitive informati<strong>on</strong><br />

An organisati<strong>on</strong> must not collect sensitive informati<strong>on</strong> 348 a about an individual unless<br />

the requirements described in Nati<strong>on</strong>al Privacy Principle 10 are met such as that the<br />

individual has c<strong>on</strong>sented or the collecti<strong>on</strong> was required or authorised by or under<br />

law.<br />

348<br />

The term “sensitive informati<strong>on</strong>” is defined in the Privacy Amendment (Private Sector) Bill 2000.<br />

130


Privacy codes<br />

An organisati<strong>on</strong> or industry body can draft its own privacy code that, if approved,<br />

will supplant the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Privacy Principles. The Privacy Commissi<strong>on</strong>er must<br />

approve all privacy codes. The Bill sets out the matters that the Privacy<br />

Commissi<strong>on</strong>er must take into account when deciding whether or not to approve a<br />

privacy code. The code must provide at least as much privacy protecti<strong>on</strong> as the<br />

Nati<strong>on</strong>al Privacy Principles.<br />

Where a code includes a procedure for making and dealing with complaints, the<br />

Privacy Commissi<strong>on</strong>er must c<strong>on</strong>sider the matters set out in the Bill such as whether<br />

the procedures meet the prescribed standards. At this stage, it is intended to<br />

prescribe the ‘Benchmarks for <strong>Industry</strong>-Based Customer Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong><br />

Schemes’ published by the C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs Divisi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, the Privacy Commissi<strong>on</strong>er intends to prepare guidelines relating to<br />

complaint handling under approved codes. These guidelines must be c<strong>on</strong>sidered<br />

where a code provides procedures for dealing with complaints.<br />

If an industry does not have its own code, then the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Privacy Principles set<br />

out in the Bill apply to those organisati<strong>on</strong>s and the Privacy Commissi<strong>on</strong>er handles all<br />

complaints to such organisati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

The complaints process and enforcement<br />

Complaints that either the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Privacy Principles or an approved code have<br />

been breached must be made in the first instance to the organisati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerned. If the<br />

individual and the organisati<strong>on</strong> are unable to reach a satisfactory soluti<strong>on</strong>, the<br />

individual may request an investigati<strong>on</strong> of the complaint to determine whether there<br />

has been an interference with their privacy.<br />

Such investigati<strong>on</strong>s will be carried out by the Privacy Commissi<strong>on</strong>er unless the<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong> is subject to an approved privacy code that nominates an independent<br />

code adjudicator body.<br />

If a complaint is upheld, the Privacy Commissi<strong>on</strong>er or the code adjudicator may<br />

make a determinati<strong>on</strong>. Such determinati<strong>on</strong>s may require certain acti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the part of<br />

the organisati<strong>on</strong>, such as to remove the individual’s name from a mailing list, or the<br />

payment of m<strong>on</strong>ey to the individual by way of compensati<strong>on</strong>. Individuals will also<br />

have the ability to apply to the Federal Magistrates Service or the Federal Court to<br />

have a determinati<strong>on</strong> enforced.<br />

Further detail c<strong>on</strong>cerning the Privacy Amendment (Private Sector) Bill 2000 can be<br />

found at:<br />

http://www.law.gov.au/privacy and http://www.aph.gov.au/legis.htm<br />

131


Summary and overview<br />

The Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth, States and Territories have legislative provisi<strong>on</strong>s capable of<br />

underpinning industry codes of practice. Examinati<strong>on</strong> of these schemes and schemes<br />

that already exist in a number of industry sectors dem<strong>on</strong>strate a range of legislative<br />

frameworks, with variati<strong>on</strong>s in approaches to development, regulati<strong>on</strong>, and<br />

enforcement of the examined codes.<br />

As recognised at the outset of this paper, the regulatory opti<strong>on</strong> of incorporating<br />

industry codes in a regulatory framework is relatively new. The opportunity to<br />

review the effectiveness of different regulatory models after several years’ operati<strong>on</strong><br />

will provide further useful informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the market circumstances and scheme<br />

features that characterise effective industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

132


Appendix D<br />

Internati<strong>on</strong>al Policy <strong>on</strong> <strong>Industry</strong> <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

… the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> will … have regard to developments in industry self-regulatory<br />

practice in other jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s … overseas.<br />

Introducti<strong>on</strong><br />

Examinati<strong>on</strong> of the regulatory policies of numerous developed countries gives a clear<br />

outline of the variety of regulatory practices in operati<strong>on</strong> within the internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment. In researching the diversity of regulatory policy, it has become evident<br />

that formal regulati<strong>on</strong> no l<strong>on</strong>ger has the appeal for governments that it did in the<br />

past. Governments are learning that regulatory policy can be limiting and costly for<br />

industry, c<strong>on</strong>sumers and indeed the government itself. The need to stay competitive<br />

within the domestic and internati<strong>on</strong>al marketplace has seen the momentum shift<br />

towards implementing alternatives to formal government regulati<strong>on</strong> and legislati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is acknowledged as <strong>on</strong>e of the most effective alternatives to<br />

formal government regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The importance in finding legitimate alternatives to restrictive government<br />

legislati<strong>on</strong> is exemplified by the research c<strong>on</strong>ducted by the Organisati<strong>on</strong> for<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Cooperati<strong>on</strong> and Development (OECD). The OECD states that the<br />

balancing of objectives for governments of developed countries is certainly a<br />

sensitive task. Governments are given the difficult task of ensuring that there is<br />

enough c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> and promoti<strong>on</strong> of social and envir<strong>on</strong>mental objectives<br />

whilst allowing industries to compete in a free market. The OECD quest to determine<br />

best regulatory practice suggests that finding the right regulatory balance is difficult,<br />

time-c<strong>on</strong>suming and requires c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> and cooperati<strong>on</strong> by all key stakeholders in<br />

the process.<br />

In identifying internati<strong>on</strong>al trends there must be c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> given to the traditi<strong>on</strong><br />

of the government, cultural practices and history of each country. These factors often<br />

have a bearing <strong>on</strong> the speed and pathway taken to regulatory reform, and indeed the<br />

very definiti<strong>on</strong> of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> and best practice. The OECD has identified that the<br />

range of policy tools and their uses are expanding as experimentati<strong>on</strong> occurs,<br />

learning is diffused, and the understanding of markets increases. However, the<br />

OECD places a caveat <strong>on</strong> this comment by stating administrators in a number of<br />

countries face risks in using relatively untried tools. Traditi<strong>on</strong>ally bureaucracies are<br />

highly c<strong>on</strong>servative and there are disincentives for public servants to be innovative.<br />

133


This paper addresses the self-regulatory policies undertaken by a number of leading<br />

countries within the OECD. Through careful explorati<strong>on</strong> of current self-regulatory<br />

policies and practices it is clear that different governments have utilised a variety of<br />

self-regulatory models to increase competiti<strong>on</strong> in the marketplace. In order to<br />

establish a comparative framework for the method by which different countries are<br />

embracing self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, this paper explores e-commerce developments within<br />

Canada, the United States of America and the United Kingdom. Through this<br />

research it becomes evident that each of these countries has embraced self-regulati<strong>on</strong><br />

as the <strong>on</strong>ly tool to deal effectively with the internati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text of e-commerce.<br />

What are interesting are the subtle differences evident in the way e-commerce<br />

self-regulatory policy is promoted to industry and c<strong>on</strong>sumers within each country.<br />

Overall, through explorati<strong>on</strong> of the regulatory models which exist within the<br />

internati<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment it becomes clear that the <strong>Australian</strong> Government and<br />

industries are am<strong>on</strong>gst the most progressive and pro-active in promoting policies<br />

that advance self-regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

OECD research<br />

The OECD has carried out a number of studies into regulatory reform and is<br />

currently in the process of c<strong>on</strong>ducting in-depth case studies into member countries to<br />

identify general trends in regulatory reform. The OECD research at this point in time<br />

has identified a number of factors that should be applied to ensure sound regulatory<br />

reform. However, in identifying universal guides to best practice, there is the<br />

recogniti<strong>on</strong> that these must be couched in the specific ec<strong>on</strong>omic, social and political<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ments of each country.<br />

The OECD has identified that many member governments may not have a str<strong>on</strong>g<br />

mandate to regulate less but have identified a universal need to regulate better. It<br />

exemplifies this commitment by stating that the Canadian Government has called<br />

this ‘regulating smarter’, while the European Commissi<strong>on</strong> has announced ‘less<br />

acti<strong>on</strong>, but better acti<strong>on</strong>’. The challenge for governments is to find the right mix of<br />

market forces and government interventi<strong>on</strong> to achieve policy objectives to ensure<br />

efficiency in changing ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

The OECD has issued guides to provide a framework under which regulatory reform<br />

should be c<strong>on</strong>ducted to assist in successful implementati<strong>on</strong>. The first of these guides<br />

is that there must be strength and c<strong>on</strong>sistency of support at the highest political level.<br />

That is, government representatives need to be c<strong>on</strong>scientious in overcoming the<br />

vested interests in both public and private sectors which benefit the status quo and<br />

resist beneficial change. Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, the government must promote a c<strong>on</strong>sultative<br />

approach, involving industry, c<strong>on</strong>sumers and other key stakeholders, when<br />

reforming regulati<strong>on</strong>s. This ensures all parties are aware of their duties and<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities as part of the structural change, in additi<strong>on</strong> to the benefits to be<br />

134


gained. In many respects, these guides reflect the process of policy formati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong><br />

industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> apparent in countries including Australia and Canada. 349<br />

As part of the broader terms of reference of regulatory reform, there is c<strong>on</strong>tinuing<br />

importance placed <strong>on</strong> governments to encourage self-regulatory practices. In this<br />

regard, implementati<strong>on</strong> of industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is c<strong>on</strong>sidered a better form of<br />

regulati<strong>on</strong> with the OECD c<strong>on</strong>ducting research into codes of corporate c<strong>on</strong>duct,<br />

exemplifying the growth and popularity of n<strong>on</strong>-legislative forms of regulati<strong>on</strong>. The<br />

OECD has broadly defined codes of corporate c<strong>on</strong>duct as ‘commitments voluntarily<br />

made by companies, associati<strong>on</strong>s or other entities, which put forth standards and<br />

principles for the c<strong>on</strong>duct of business activities. 350<br />

This OECD research relied <strong>on</strong> informati<strong>on</strong> supplied by member countries and drew a<br />

number of interesting c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s about the variety of codes that are currently in<br />

operati<strong>on</strong>. These included:<br />

¾ For some codes adherence is a prerequisite for membership in a business<br />

associati<strong>on</strong>, partnership of stakeholders or for access to recogniti<strong>on</strong> marks, such<br />

as logos or labels.<br />

¾ The effectiveness of codes in influencing the behaviour of corporati<strong>on</strong>s depends<br />

<strong>on</strong> a str<strong>on</strong>g enforcement mechanism.<br />

¾ A majority of codes surveyed relied <strong>on</strong> internal m<strong>on</strong>itoring. For situati<strong>on</strong>s of<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-compliance, codes often provide for a wide range of possible acti<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

including correcti<strong>on</strong> of the c<strong>on</strong>duct in questi<strong>on</strong> and terminati<strong>on</strong> of existing<br />

business relati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

¾ More generally, third parties do not play a prominent role in code<br />

administrati<strong>on</strong>. Government authorities were found to be involved in some<br />

codes developed by professi<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>s and in <strong>on</strong>ly a few other cases.<br />

In light of this research it becomes apparent that self-regulati<strong>on</strong> for many countries is<br />

still in a developmental phase with the roles of key stakeholders not clearly defined.<br />

The United States of America (US)<br />

The OECD, as part of a broader research into regulatory reform, undertook a study<br />

<strong>on</strong> the regulatory policies of the US Government. An interesting observati<strong>on</strong> made<br />

by this study is that the US, a country known for its str<strong>on</strong>g support of free markets, is<br />

not ‘less regulated’ than other OECD countries but ‘differently regulated’ 351 . The<br />

349 A number of other useful OECD policy recommendati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> regulatory reform can be accessed<br />

at www.oecd.org/publicati<strong>on</strong>s/Pol_brief/9804_pol.htm.<br />

350 Further informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> this report can be accessed at OECD, 1999, Codes of Corporate C<strong>on</strong>duct:<br />

An Inventory, OECD, Working Party of the Trade Committee, Paris.<br />

351 For further informati<strong>on</strong> please see OECD, 1999, Regulatory Reform in the United States. OECD,<br />

Paris.<br />

135


study asserted that the US Government tends to impose rigid, complex and highly<br />

detailed regulati<strong>on</strong>s and formalities that impose unnecessarily high costs <strong>on</strong> all<br />

stakeholders. In fact, self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is specifically authorised by formal regulati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

a number of industries, including securities and the envir<strong>on</strong>ment. It is identified that<br />

the government is the instituti<strong>on</strong> that places emphasis <strong>on</strong> this formal method of<br />

encouraging industries to attempt to be self-regulating, rather than industry or other<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-governmental groups. In drawing these c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s, it is identified that the<br />

quality of regulati<strong>on</strong> varies widely due to the large number of outdated laws which<br />

systematically tend to be ineffective, the adversarial nature of the American<br />

law-based system which fails to encourage development of voluntary codes and the<br />

problems caused by the overlap of federal/state jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

The US practice of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> differs from <strong>Australian</strong> self-regulatory models<br />

which are typically developed and administered by industry associati<strong>on</strong>s. US<br />

companies may adopt corporate codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct, binding themselves to certain<br />

standards or ethical principles that their competitors would not necessarily uphold.<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumers in the US are familiar with essentially self-regulatory schemes that tend<br />

to cross industry boundaries.<br />

An example of a US scheme that supports and administrates self-regulati<strong>on</strong> across<br />

numerous industries is the Council of Better Business Bureaus (CBBB) 352 . The CBBB is<br />

a private, n<strong>on</strong>-profit organisati<strong>on</strong> supported by membership fees paid by business<br />

and professi<strong>on</strong>al groups. The CBBB missi<strong>on</strong> is to promote and foster the highest<br />

ethical relati<strong>on</strong>ship between businesses and the public through voluntary<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. CBBB states that corporate America has much to benefit from<br />

voluntary self-regulati<strong>on</strong> of business practices, in comparis<strong>on</strong> to costly government<br />

legislati<strong>on</strong>. The acceptance, and promoti<strong>on</strong> of this self-regulatory policy is applicable<br />

<strong>on</strong>ce a business joins the CBBB under the ‘Uniform Standards of Membership’. The<br />

CBBB has a number of roles including:<br />

¾ providing businesses with an opti<strong>on</strong>al nati<strong>on</strong>al dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> scheme,<br />

involving c<strong>on</strong>ciliati<strong>on</strong>, mediati<strong>on</strong> and arbitrati<strong>on</strong>, to resolve c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

complaints in particular circumstances;<br />

¾ generating reports about companies (members and n<strong>on</strong>-members) for<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers to make an informed choice about goods and services (however the<br />

CBBB does not endorse any particular product or company); and<br />

¾ investigating complaints about misleading advertising claims, through the<br />

self-regulated Nati<strong>on</strong>al Advertising Divisi<strong>on</strong>, and determining whether such<br />

claims can be substantiated.<br />

352 For more informati<strong>on</strong> about the Better Business Bureau please see http://www.bbb.com/.<br />

136


Canada<br />

In c<strong>on</strong>trast, the Canadian Government has been busy in providing a policy<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment that promotes and is c<strong>on</strong>ducive to implementati<strong>on</strong> of industry<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. The Canadian Government identified the need to encourage<br />

industries to self-regulate due to government budgetary pressures and the growing<br />

recogniti<strong>on</strong> of the limitati<strong>on</strong>s of c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al command and c<strong>on</strong>trol approaches over<br />

industry. In order to address this imperative the government moved towards<br />

encouraging discussi<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>gst the key stakeholders to identify the best way to<br />

encourage industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. The Canadian Government hosted a Symposium<br />

<strong>on</strong> Voluntary Codes in 1996 353 that brought together representatives from industry,<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups, n<strong>on</strong>-government organisati<strong>on</strong>s, academia and other government<br />

departments. One of the main objectives of the Symposium was to develop<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sensus regarding the way self-regulati<strong>on</strong> could be successfully implemented. It<br />

was recommended that <strong>on</strong>e of the possible steps was to develop a ‘Voluntary Codes<br />

Guide’ akin to that in place in Australia. 354<br />

There was general agreement by the key stakeholders that there were certain<br />

elements essential to a fair and workable self-regulatory system. One element<br />

promoted by c<strong>on</strong>sumer associati<strong>on</strong>s present at the Symposium was the need for the<br />

Canadian Government to be involved in the development of each code and provisi<strong>on</strong><br />

of adequate support of the code (proceeding al<strong>on</strong>g the lines of Australia’s definiti<strong>on</strong><br />

of co-regulati<strong>on</strong>).<br />

Other Symposium members advocated that for the government to be a successful<br />

participant in the process of code development, the role of the government needed to<br />

be clearly defined from the beginning to avoid any c<strong>on</strong>fusi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> behalf of those<br />

involved in the process and to avoid government liability in n<strong>on</strong>-compliance<br />

situati<strong>on</strong>s. These discussi<strong>on</strong>s acted as a catalyst for the Canadian Government to<br />

identify the different roles it could play in the process of effective and efficient code<br />

development. These can be summarised as:<br />

Catalyst<br />

Government representatives can encourage parties to explore voluntary approaches<br />

even if laws or regulati<strong>on</strong>s are not imminent. Government research, analysis and<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s can reveal enough c<strong>on</strong>cern to stimulate acti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

353 For further informati<strong>on</strong> please see <strong>Industry</strong> Canada 1996, Symposium <strong>on</strong> Voluntary Codes,<br />

Ottawa, September.<br />

354 For further informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> this guide please see Codes of C<strong>on</strong>duct Policy Framework, released by<br />

the then Minister for Customs and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs in March 1998.<br />

137


Facilitator<br />

Governments can provide meeting rooms, telec<strong>on</strong>ference facilities, informati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

advice and in some cases, financial assistance, in the early stages of code<br />

development.<br />

Endorser<br />

In some circumstances, government departments or agencies can explicitly endorse a<br />

particular code or associati<strong>on</strong> that satisfies the provisi<strong>on</strong>s of a code. However, it is<br />

important that clear legal authority for such endorsement exists.<br />

Broker<br />

The government can negotiate to ensure that all of the relevant parties are involved.<br />

Provider of framework rules and regulatory support<br />

A regulatory authority could insist <strong>on</strong> adherence to voluntary codes as a c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

issuing a licence. Enforcement and procurement policies can encourage voluntary<br />

code compliance.<br />

Direct participant<br />

The government may also act as a direct participant in the process if this is acceptable<br />

and relevant.<br />

The Canadian Government recognises that it has an important functi<strong>on</strong> in<br />

encouraging, developing and supporting self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in industries through these<br />

roles. However, to ensure that the government is effective in their chosen role it must<br />

clearly explain their role and resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities to the code developers, be open and<br />

clear about the status of the code and the extent of the governments liability in<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-compliance situati<strong>on</strong>s. In additi<strong>on</strong>, government officials must be fair and<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sistent in all dealings and must ensure that there will be no opportunity for<br />

statutes to be c<strong>on</strong>travened and that all m<strong>on</strong>ey spent <strong>on</strong> assistance is in the public<br />

benefit. Flexibility and the opportunity for codes to change to remain effective must<br />

also be recognised by government as best practice. 355<br />

The Canadian Office of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs recently released a publicati<strong>on</strong> that<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tains a framework to evaluate the effectiveness of voluntary codes, and<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequently identify areas where code operati<strong>on</strong> could be improved. It is suggested<br />

that the evaluative framework could be used by firms, industry organisati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

workers, public interest groups, citizens, government and others to evaluate a<br />

355 For further informati<strong>on</strong> please see Office of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs, 1998, Voluntary Codes: A Guide for<br />

their Development and Use, <strong>Industry</strong> Canada.<br />

138


diverse range of codes in operati<strong>on</strong>. An Evaluative Framework for Voluntary Codes 356 ,<br />

details a number of performance indicators that should be used to undertake a<br />

thorough analysis of a code. These include the need to examine due process,<br />

relevance, success and possible alternative approaches to the code. The framework<br />

suggests that each performance indicator is not necessarily relevant to all codes due<br />

to differing objectives and envir<strong>on</strong>mental circumstances. However, the framework is<br />

a useful tool to provide assistance in evaluating codes to ensure the objectives of the<br />

code are being met, the code is still relevant and identifying whether the code is the<br />

most appropriate form of regulati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The Canadian Government experience highlights that there is still an <strong>on</strong>going debate<br />

about the most appropriate role government departments should play in<br />

self-regulatory development and the most appropriate manner by which codes<br />

should be enforced. To further explore these issues, the Canadian C<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

Measures Committee will be establishing a task force to investigate market-based<br />

approaches to c<strong>on</strong>sumer redress. The task force aims to benchmark best practices and<br />

work with business and c<strong>on</strong>sumer organisati<strong>on</strong>s to develop tools to encourage<br />

business and c<strong>on</strong>sumers to use more effective mechanisms for complaints<br />

preventi<strong>on</strong>, handling and dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>. 357<br />

From an <strong>Australian</strong> perspective the potential roles that could be undertaken by the<br />

Canadian Government reflect the regulatory spectrum. 358 Both Governments have<br />

clearly identified that industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is desirable and have developed policy<br />

frameworks which involve government playing a role in development and support<br />

of voluntary codes. There is clear recogniti<strong>on</strong> that for self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to work there<br />

needs to be flexibility built into any code development and that partnership between<br />

key stakeholders is an essential element for successful implementati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

United Kingdom<br />

The United Kingdom (UK) has embraced a different self-regulatory policy model to<br />

Canada and Australia. As an important comp<strong>on</strong>ent of their self-regulatory policy, the<br />

UK Government has asserted that its government agency, the Office of Fair Trading<br />

(OFT), will take a more active role in code approval. The broad framework for<br />

government agencies assuming an active role in granting seals of approval for codes<br />

was outlined in the Department of Trade and <strong>Industry</strong>’s (DTI) White Paper 359 . The<br />

White Paper proposed that the self-regulatory policy would incorporate:<br />

356 For more informati<strong>on</strong> please see Office of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs, <strong>Industry</strong> Canada 2000, An<br />

Evaluative Framework for Voluntary Codes, Ontario.<br />

357 For further informati<strong>on</strong> please see Office of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs, <strong>Industry</strong> Canada Fall 1999 ⎯<br />

Winter 2000, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Quarterly, Volume 5, Number 1.<br />

358 For further informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the regulatory spectrum please see Codes of C<strong>on</strong>duct Policy Framework,<br />

released by the then Minister for Customs and C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs in March 1998.<br />

359 For further informati<strong>on</strong> please see DTI, 1999, C<strong>on</strong>fident C<strong>on</strong>sumers: Modern Markets, DTI, UK.<br />

139


¾ promoti<strong>on</strong> of the core principles and encourage good practice by keeping them<br />

up-to-date;<br />

¾ publicising approval or rejecti<strong>on</strong> of codes as decisi<strong>on</strong>s are made;<br />

¾ publicising to c<strong>on</strong>sumers the benefits of the overall scheme and the benefits of<br />

dealing with businesses that comply with approved codes;<br />

¾ providing and marketing a seal of approval for approved codes so that<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers can see whether a trader is committed to code standards; and<br />

¾ the ability to remove the seal from codes that fail to deliver.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, the White Paper outlined that these new approval mechanisms, coupled<br />

with an effective marketing campaign promoting the value of codes, would<br />

encourage businesses to sign up and comply with effective codes. Those businesses<br />

choosing not to comply with a code will be subjected to the new procedures for<br />

dealing with unfair trading practices. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the UK Government, through<br />

implementati<strong>on</strong> of this scheme, stated that they did not see the need to create a<br />

reserve power to impose a code, as in the case of Australia.<br />

The framework of this self-regulatory policy has been carefully scrutinised by a<br />

number of government agencies within the UK. In September 1997, the Regulatory<br />

Impact Unit — a part of the UK Cabinet Office — commissi<strong>on</strong>ed the ‘Better<br />

Regulati<strong>on</strong> Task Force (BRTF)’ to advise the Government <strong>on</strong> acti<strong>on</strong> to improve the<br />

effectiveness and credibility of government regulati<strong>on</strong>. The Task Force, through the<br />

release of their <strong>Self</strong>-Regulati<strong>on</strong> Interim <strong>Report</strong> in October 1999 360 , expressed reservati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

about the proposals set out in the DTI White Paper. The main cause of their c<strong>on</strong>cern<br />

was the power granted to the OFT to approve codes. The Task Force suggested that<br />

this policy might increase risk in regards to lines of accountability being undermined<br />

if the Government is seen to endorse codes of practice over which it has no <strong>on</strong>-going<br />

supervisi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

However, further advice from the DTI 361 has revealed that there was apparently a<br />

misunderstanding underlying the BRTF Interim <strong>Report</strong> regarding informati<strong>on</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>tained in the White Paper. This is in regards to the proposed new powers for the<br />

Director General of Fair Trading. The proposals in the White Paper make it clear that<br />

the new powers for the OFT to approve codes of practice will be accompanied by<br />

obligati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> code sp<strong>on</strong>sors to report regularly to the OFT <strong>on</strong> performance of the<br />

code and will give the Director General power to remove approval from ‘bad’ codes.<br />

Hence, the OFT will play a role in <strong>on</strong>going code supervisi<strong>on</strong> and lines of<br />

accountability will be firmly established.<br />

360 For further informati<strong>on</strong> please see Better Regulati<strong>on</strong> Task Force, 1999, <strong>Self</strong>-Regulati<strong>on</strong> Interim<br />

<strong>Report</strong>, Cabinet Office-Regulatory Impact Office, UK.<br />

361 Informati<strong>on</strong> obtained directly from the Department of Trade and <strong>Industry</strong> <strong>on</strong> 23 March 2000.<br />

140


Ministers have also been asked to c<strong>on</strong>sult the BRTF regularly, and at an earlier stage,<br />

about new policy proposals in regards to introducti<strong>on</strong> of regulati<strong>on</strong>. This will ensure<br />

that the flow of new regulati<strong>on</strong> is c<strong>on</strong>trolled and that an adequate amount of time is<br />

allocated to c<strong>on</strong>sult with key stakeholders.<br />

The development of self-regulatory policy is still c<strong>on</strong>tinuing with the OFT working<br />

<strong>on</strong> the mechanisms by which the new code regime will be delivered, in c<strong>on</strong>juncti<strong>on</strong><br />

with an assessment of the likely costs to industry. The DTI is currently working <strong>on</strong><br />

the draft Bill that will create the powers for this code seal of approval. At present the<br />

OFT is working towards the necessary legislati<strong>on</strong> being passed by June 2001. The<br />

DTI is also supporting a study by the UK Trade Associati<strong>on</strong> Forum <strong>on</strong> attitudes to<br />

this new policy. To date, the resp<strong>on</strong>ses from this study have been very positive.<br />

However, there was some c<strong>on</strong>cern expressed about the possible cost implicati<strong>on</strong>s for<br />

industry and about the independent/c<strong>on</strong>sumer element in redress mechanisms. The<br />

DTI and OFT are seeking to address these c<strong>on</strong>cerns in the course of implementati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

It is obvious that there has been c<strong>on</strong>siderable debate within the UK as to the best way<br />

for the government to encourage industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. From the large volume of<br />

resources and time spent by the government it is apparent that regulatory reform is<br />

an important policy initiative. However, to date, the UK Government has followed a<br />

more direct path in development, promoti<strong>on</strong> and enforcement of codes <strong>on</strong>ce they are<br />

developed. In many resects the ‘hands-<strong>on</strong>’ approach embraced by the government is<br />

more closely related to co-regulati<strong>on</strong> in the <strong>Australian</strong> regulatory spectrum.<br />

New Zealand<br />

The New Zealand Ministry of Fair Trading is a member of the Ministerial Council for<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs, also comprising <strong>Australian</strong> Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth, State and Territory<br />

Ministers for C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs. New Zealand has thus been closely involved in<br />

Australia’s policy development in relati<strong>on</strong> to codes of practice. New Zealand has<br />

published its own policy guidelines <strong>on</strong> the role of industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong>. 362 New Zealand has also embraced self-regulati<strong>on</strong> as a strategy<br />

for c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> in the <strong>on</strong>line marketplace, having recently released a model<br />

code for internet traders that draws heavily up<strong>on</strong> Australia’s work in the field. 363<br />

European Uni<strong>on</strong><br />

The European Uni<strong>on</strong> (EU) has been cautious in embracing self-regulati<strong>on</strong> for<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> in the c<strong>on</strong>text of member countries having generally<br />

implemented str<strong>on</strong>g c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> laws. However, the EU has recently<br />

commissi<strong>on</strong>ed a study from an internati<strong>on</strong>al lawyers network to ‘identify best<br />

362 For more informati<strong>on</strong> please see http://www.c<strong>on</strong>sumer-ministry.govt.nz/dp_selfreg.html.<br />

363 For more informati<strong>on</strong> please see<br />

http://www.c<strong>on</strong>sumer-ministry.govt.nz/dp_ecommerce_statusreport.htm.<br />

141


practice in soft law and to analyse how this best practice can be made to work for<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers in the European Uni<strong>on</strong>’, particularly in relati<strong>on</strong> to utilities, but also<br />

looking at advertising and direct selling practices. The EU study will cover much of<br />

the same ground as the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Taskforce</str<strong>on</strong>g> inquiry.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, the EU has been busy developing and implementing other forms of<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. Included in these initiatives is the development of guidelines for<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-judicial dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> (such as industry ombudsmen) in members’<br />

countries. 364 The European Commissi<strong>on</strong> (EC) is also implementing measures to<br />

strengthen c<strong>on</strong>sumer capacity to take collective acti<strong>on</strong>. A commitment has been<br />

made by the EC to provide resources for c<strong>on</strong>sumer training, informati<strong>on</strong> and<br />

educati<strong>on</strong>, whilst promoting more effective dialogue am<strong>on</strong>g c<strong>on</strong>sumer organisati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

business and the Commissi<strong>on</strong>’s advisory committee. Interestingly, the EC, in<br />

c<strong>on</strong>juncti<strong>on</strong> with the UK, has advocated for c<strong>on</strong>sumers playing a role in m<strong>on</strong>itoring<br />

and enforcing existing legislati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

EU countries have shown particular interest in industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in the c<strong>on</strong>text<br />

of electr<strong>on</strong>ic commerce, with the Netherlands being <strong>on</strong>e of the first nati<strong>on</strong>s to<br />

develop an industry code of c<strong>on</strong>duct in this area. The use of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

e-commerce is discussed in more detail below.<br />

Electr<strong>on</strong>ic commerce (e-commerce) case study<br />

This paper will now briefly examine current regulatory developments in the<br />

e-commerce marketplace focussing <strong>on</strong> the OECD countries of the US, Canada and<br />

the UK. These particular countries provide a useful comparative framework for<br />

self-regulatory policy initiatives. Indeed, the method by which each has sought to<br />

embrace e-commerce self-regulati<strong>on</strong> to date does not vary dramatically, but there are<br />

subtle policy differences which are indicative of a different way of promoting<br />

regulatory reform in general.<br />

E-commerce, as an increasingly popular method of purchasing merchandise <strong>on</strong>line,<br />

has required governments of developed countries to simultaneously formulate<br />

policies that provide adequate c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong>. At the internati<strong>on</strong>al level,<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> of e-commerce is c<strong>on</strong>sidered as the <strong>on</strong>ly useful opti<strong>on</strong> because <strong>on</strong>line<br />

trades are increasingly crossing jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>al boundaries. The formal regulati<strong>on</strong>s and<br />

laws of each country are suddenly not applicable to the explosi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>on</strong>line traders<br />

located in another country with different rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s. Hence, a challenging<br />

comp<strong>on</strong>ent of any government driven policy regarding e-commerce is the need to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sider the dynamics of the internati<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment.<br />

The OECD has advocated the need to take a global approach to c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong><br />

as part of a transparent effective and efficient self-regulatory framework for<br />

364 For more informati<strong>on</strong> please see<br />

http://www.europa.eu.int/comm/dg24/policy/developments/acce_just/acce_just02_en.html<br />

142


e-commerce. In order to facilitate an e-commerce system that ensures c<strong>on</strong>sumers are<br />

protected, in additi<strong>on</strong> to encouraging free trade, the OECD has published general<br />

recommendati<strong>on</strong>s and guidelines intended for governments, businesses, and<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers. 365 The OECD promotes these recommendati<strong>on</strong>s as the minimum of any<br />

effective e-commerce policy and they should not restrict any country from adopting<br />

more stringent provisi<strong>on</strong>s to protect c<strong>on</strong>sumers <strong>on</strong>line. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the OECD urges<br />

member governments to review and, if necessary, promote self-regulatory principles<br />

to encourage development of effective self-regulatory mechanisms that c<strong>on</strong>tain<br />

specific, substantive rules for dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> and compliance mechanisms.<br />

Canada has adopted an e-commerce policy framework that c<strong>on</strong>sists mostly of<br />

industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> rather than formal government regulati<strong>on</strong>. The Canadian<br />

Government is aware of the global reach of e-commerce and has maintained that it<br />

will be c<strong>on</strong>sistent with approaches to c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> agreed to by the<br />

internati<strong>on</strong>al community. 366 A Canadian Government Working Group has promoted<br />

a system that calls for protecti<strong>on</strong> for c<strong>on</strong>sumers shopping <strong>on</strong>line equivalent to that<br />

available in traditi<strong>on</strong>al forms of commerce. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> within this industry<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment has been promoted as a legitimate regulatory instrument. Future work<br />

identified by the government will involve harm<strong>on</strong>ising c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong><br />

legislati<strong>on</strong>, developing c<strong>on</strong>sumer educati<strong>on</strong> and informati<strong>on</strong> products, and<br />

identifying ways to work with the private sector to develop trust marks for merchant<br />

certificati<strong>on</strong> and <strong>on</strong>line c<strong>on</strong>sumer redress mechanisms.<br />

The United States Government is promoting a number of principles as part of its<br />

e-commerce strategy. Included in the principles is the need for the private sector to<br />

lead the way in e-commerce, that government should avoid undue restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong><br />

e-commerce and where government involvement is needed, its aim should be to<br />

support and enforce a predictable, minimalist, c<strong>on</strong>sistent and simple legal<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>ment. 367<br />

Since the introducti<strong>on</strong> of these principles, the US has attempted to increase c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

protecti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>line by encouraging industry self-regulati<strong>on</strong> in c<strong>on</strong>juncti<strong>on</strong> with the<br />

aggressive prosecuti<strong>on</strong> of fraudulent practices and misleading advertising in the<br />

<strong>on</strong>line marketplace under existing c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> laws. The government<br />

believes that the numerous codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct developed and ultimately enforced by<br />

the private sector is the most effective way to protect privacy <strong>on</strong>line. 368 An example of<br />

the private sector developing codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct for c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> is<br />

365 For further informati<strong>on</strong> please see OECD, 1998, Recommendati<strong>on</strong> of the OECD Council C<strong>on</strong>cerning<br />

Guidelines for C<strong>on</strong>sumer Protecti<strong>on</strong> in the C<strong>on</strong>text of Electr<strong>on</strong>ic Commerce, OECD, Paris.<br />

366 For more informati<strong>on</strong> please see Working Group <strong>on</strong> Electr<strong>on</strong>ic Commerce and C<strong>on</strong>sumers,<br />

1999, Principles of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Protecti<strong>on</strong> for Electr<strong>on</strong>ic Commerce: A Canadian Framework, Ottawa,<br />

<strong>Industry</strong> Canada.<br />

367 For more informati<strong>on</strong> please see White House, 1997, A Framework for Global Electr<strong>on</strong>ic Commerce,<br />

White House, Washingt<strong>on</strong>.<br />

368 For more informati<strong>on</strong> please see US Government Working Group <strong>on</strong> Electr<strong>on</strong>ic Commerce,<br />

1999, Towards Digital E-Quality, 2nd Annual <strong>Report</strong>.<br />

143


exemplified by BBBOnline. 369 The BBBOnline seal assures users that businesses<br />

displaying the seals follow credible and effective <strong>on</strong>line practices. However, the<br />

proliferati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>on</strong>line trust seals within the US has become problematic in the sense<br />

that <strong>on</strong>ce a decisi<strong>on</strong> is made regarding breaches of <strong>on</strong>e seal of which a company is a<br />

member, the decisi<strong>on</strong> may not be recognised by other seals subscribed to by the<br />

company. This problem is not unique to the US e-commerce market and the issues<br />

involved have yet to be clarified.<br />

However, the United Kingdom has aimed at diminishing this possibility through<br />

introducti<strong>on</strong> of a more regulated and uniform approach to website seals. In this<br />

regard the United Kingdom has taken a slightly different route to Canada, the US<br />

and Australia in the e-commerce field. Although the overriding policy thrust in the<br />

e-commerce arena is recognised as c<strong>on</strong>taining elements of self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, the UK<br />

promotes its policy as a co-regulatory approach with success in e-commerce declared<br />

as <strong>on</strong>e of a shared enterprise. 370 Hence, the role of government includes provisi<strong>on</strong> of a<br />

light-touch regulati<strong>on</strong> in the electr<strong>on</strong>ic market. This co-regulatory partnership<br />

between government and business encapsulates public policy objectives but tasks<br />

industry to design and operate self-regulatory soluti<strong>on</strong>s. The government stands<br />

behind industry ready to take statutory acti<strong>on</strong> if necessary.<br />

An example of where this co-regulatory approach has been introduced in the UK is<br />

in the area of webseals. The UK Government, in 1999, asked the Alliance for<br />

Electr<strong>on</strong>ic Business and the C<strong>on</strong>sumers’ Associati<strong>on</strong> to work together to set up a<br />

self-regulatory scheme to address the needs of c<strong>on</strong>sumers transacting <strong>on</strong>line. The<br />

result was TrustUK which has aimed to pull together various schemes and hallmarks<br />

in order to end c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>fusi<strong>on</strong> over legitimate and illegitimate seals. TrustUK is<br />

a n<strong>on</strong>-profit organisati<strong>on</strong> run by industry but with the support and backing of the<br />

UK Government. 371<br />

In summary, it will be necessary for all governments to keep the regulatory<br />

framework under review so that c<strong>on</strong>sumers have effective protecti<strong>on</strong> when engaging<br />

in e-commerce. <strong>Self</strong>-regulati<strong>on</strong> has been recognised as having an important role to<br />

play in c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong> given the global nature of e-commerce. As cross-border<br />

shopping increases there will be a growing need for internati<strong>on</strong>al co-operati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong><br />

questi<strong>on</strong>s of enforcement, dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> and redress. Businesses, c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>s, governments and other bodies have significant parts to play in<br />

informing and educating c<strong>on</strong>sumers about how they are protected in the new<br />

marketplace.<br />

369 More informati<strong>on</strong> regarding BBBOnline can be found at http://www.bbb<strong>on</strong>line.com/.<br />

370 Please see UK Cabinet Office, 1999, A Performance and Innovati<strong>on</strong> <strong>Report</strong>.<br />

371 For further informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> TrustUK please see http://www.trustuk.org.uk/.<br />

144


Future trends in internati<strong>on</strong>al self-regulatory policy<br />

<strong>Self</strong>-regulatory policy has been promoted by the OECD as a legitimate alternative to<br />

formal regulati<strong>on</strong> and is being embraced by member countries at different rates. Each<br />

country reviewed in this paper gives a valuable insight into the current state of<br />

affairs in regulatory reform. Clearly, countries such as Australia, Canada and the UK<br />

are more actively embracing self-regulati<strong>on</strong>, with each government researching and<br />

reviewing best self-regulatory practice. However, in general it is apparent that<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is becoming an accepted form of government regulatory policy as the<br />

advantages are beneficial to all stakeholders.<br />

An issue which is currently being discussed in a number of countries is the role that<br />

each stakeholder should play in the development and implementati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

self-regulati<strong>on</strong>. There is a body of knowledge growing as to the necessary and<br />

valuable c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> that c<strong>on</strong>sumers can make to successful self-regulatory schemes.<br />

This is well illustrated by the UK White Paper that puts c<strong>on</strong>sumers <strong>on</strong> centre stage,<br />

through recogniti<strong>on</strong> that well-informed and c<strong>on</strong>fident c<strong>on</strong>sumers are good for<br />

business. To ensure c<strong>on</strong>sumers are able voice their opini<strong>on</strong>s, the UK government has<br />

aimed to stimulate the Nati<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>sumer Council, an independent c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>, and provide training support for 5000 new volunteers to effectively<br />

represent the c<strong>on</strong>sumer by bringing the c<strong>on</strong>sumer voice more fully into policy<br />

making. Canada has also focussed <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumer c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to policy development<br />

particularly in the area of voluntary codes, in c<strong>on</strong>juncti<strong>on</strong> with n<strong>on</strong>-governmental<br />

organisati<strong>on</strong>s and the private sector, to ensure c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong>. 372<br />

The role to be assumed by government during the self-regulatory process is<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sidered malleable, and without sufficient clarificati<strong>on</strong> during code development<br />

and implementati<strong>on</strong>, may unintenti<strong>on</strong>ally become a c<strong>on</strong>tentious issues. Although the<br />

definiti<strong>on</strong> of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> implies certain limitati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the role that governments<br />

can assume <strong>on</strong>ce a voluntary scheme is implemented, the boundaries are still being<br />

explored by all stakeholders. What is currently identified as essential to the<br />

formati<strong>on</strong> of voluntary codes, is the need for governments to clearly outline the role<br />

they will assume as a stakeholder, in c<strong>on</strong>juncti<strong>on</strong> with industry, business and<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers. Realistically, the role of the government is fluid depending <strong>on</strong> the needs<br />

of industries and c<strong>on</strong>sumers, and the set of market circumstances to be addressed.<br />

It must also be recognised that industry will often take the lead in developing and<br />

implementing self-regulatory practices separate to government policy. Indeed, the<br />

acti<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>on</strong>e industry may act as a catalyst for similar industries in other countries<br />

to follow suite. An example of an industry which has been pro-active in taking the<br />

lead in introducing self-regulatory policy is the Canadian Chemical Producers’<br />

Associati<strong>on</strong> (CCPA) and its Resp<strong>on</strong>sible Care initiative. 373 The CCPA introduced<br />

372 For further informati<strong>on</strong> please see Office of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Affairs, <strong>Industry</strong> Canada Fall 1999 ⎯<br />

Winter 2000, C<strong>on</strong>sumer Quarterly, Volume 5, Number 1.<br />

373 For more informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the CCPA and Resp<strong>on</strong>sible Care program please see<br />

http://www.ccpa.ca/.<br />

145


Resp<strong>on</strong>sible Care in 1985 and it has since become a global alliance with over<br />

40 countries participating in the scheme. Each company which subscribes to the<br />

Resp<strong>on</strong>sible Care ethic is required to abide by six codes of practice which c<strong>on</strong>tain<br />

more than 150 requirements. Verificati<strong>on</strong> checks are undertaken every three years <strong>on</strong><br />

each member-company of the CCPA to ensure the codes are being followed. There<br />

are other examples of industry espousing the virtues of self-regulati<strong>on</strong> and it can be<br />

deducted that industry initiative is an important comp<strong>on</strong>ent in delivering sound<br />

regulatory reform.<br />

Another example of a global voluntary self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is the work c<strong>on</strong>ducted by the<br />

Internati<strong>on</strong>al Organisati<strong>on</strong> for Standardisati<strong>on</strong> (ISO). 374 The ISO is a<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-governmental, worldwide federati<strong>on</strong> of nati<strong>on</strong>al standards bodies from<br />

130 countries that formulates and implements internati<strong>on</strong>ally agreed voluntary<br />

standards across a variety of goods and services. The ISO has a Committee <strong>on</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer policy dedicated to investigating the benefits to c<strong>on</strong>sumers from<br />

standardisati<strong>on</strong>. The Committee provides informati<strong>on</strong>, advice and training <strong>on</strong><br />

n<strong>on</strong>-technical c<strong>on</strong>sumer standards to assist in c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong>. The Committee<br />

also provides a forum for the exchange of experience <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

arranging implementati<strong>on</strong> of standards in the c<strong>on</strong>sumer field and resp<strong>on</strong>ding to<br />

other issues which effect c<strong>on</strong>sumers in nati<strong>on</strong>al and internati<strong>on</strong>al standardisati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

This paper illustrates that internati<strong>on</strong>al policy <strong>on</strong> self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is just coming into<br />

its own in a number of countries, as self-regulati<strong>on</strong> is recognised as beneficial to<br />

industry, c<strong>on</strong>sumers and government. It is also each of these stakeholders which<br />

need to be involved in the development and implementati<strong>on</strong> of self-regulatory<br />

policies to ensure acceptance and maintenance of the schemes. With countries such<br />

as Australia and Canada forging ahead by streamlining regulati<strong>on</strong> policy and<br />

researching elements of successful self-regulatory schemes, they not <strong>on</strong>ly exemplify<br />

how ‘good’ self-regulati<strong>on</strong> should work, but also have an opportunity to market it <strong>on</strong><br />

the world stage through forums such as the OECD.<br />

374 For more informati<strong>on</strong> please see www.iso.ch.<br />

146

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!