02.02.2013 Views

Forecasting and Policy Making (Paper) - Center for Financial Studies

Forecasting and Policy Making (Paper) - Center for Financial Studies

Forecasting and Policy Making (Paper) - Center for Financial Studies

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

of upward <strong>and</strong> downward risks. In the case of upward risks, raising the interest rate would become<br />

more likely, than when the MPC’s assessment points to symmetric uncertainty or downward risks to<br />

the inflation <strong>for</strong>ecast. The adjustment of the uncertainty b<strong>and</strong>s by the MPC could be useful to account<br />

<strong>for</strong> structural changes or additional variables not taken into account by the model <strong>and</strong> past <strong>for</strong>ecast<br />

errors.<br />

3 The role of <strong>for</strong>ecasts in policy: From Tinbergen <strong>and</strong> Theil to Taylor-<br />

style rules <strong>and</strong> optimal <strong>for</strong>ecast targeting<br />

In his <strong>for</strong>mal treatment of economic policy, Tinbergen (1952) describes economic policy as the max-<br />

imization of a collective ophelimity function by the government. This function contains a number of<br />

variables that the policy maker wants to influence but that are not directly under her control. These<br />

variables are called targets. <strong>Policy</strong> is implemented by manipulating variables that may be directly<br />

controlled by the policy maker—so-called control or instrument variables. Tinbergen (1952) differ-<br />

entiates between quantitative <strong>and</strong> qualitative policy changes. Qualitative changes imply a change in<br />

the economic structure. Examples are the dissolution of a monopoly, the introduction of a customs<br />

union or a monetary union. Thus, qualitative policy involves choosing from a finite number of policy<br />

alternatives. Quantitative policy changes are defined as adjusting certain policy parameters or instru-<br />

ments such as taxes, government expenditures or interest rates to achieve policy goals within a given<br />

economic structure. Conveniently, Tinbergen (1952) lists the following steps <strong>for</strong> the proper conduct<br />

of economic policy:<br />

(i) choose a collective preference indicator;<br />

(ii) deduce targets <strong>for</strong> economic policy from this indicator;<br />

(iii) choose adequate instruments <strong>for</strong> achieving the targets;<br />

(iv) determine quantitative values of the instrument variables;<br />

(v) <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong>mulate the connection between the targets <strong>and</strong> the instruments <strong>and</strong> the structure of the<br />

economy.<br />

With regard to <strong>for</strong>ecasts, Theil (1958, p.3) stresses that<br />

”A realistic analysis of the relationship between <strong>for</strong>ecasts <strong>and</strong> policy must be based on<br />

the assumption of several variables controlled <strong>and</strong> not controlled by the policy-maker, of<br />

their interrelationships, (<strong>and</strong>) of the policy-maker’s preferences which serve to <strong>for</strong>malize<br />

the optimality criterion” .<br />

In the following, we focus on quantitative monetary policy in Tinbergen’s nomenclature <strong>and</strong><br />

present a simple framework <strong>for</strong> relating central bank objectives, decisions, models <strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong>ecasts.<br />

12

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!