24.03.2013 Views

Intermediaries in Information Economies - Communication, Culture ...

Intermediaries in Information Economies - Communication, Culture ...

Intermediaries in Information Economies - Communication, Culture ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

INTERMEDIARIES IN INFORMATION ECONOMIES<br />

A Thesis<br />

submitted to the Faculty of the<br />

Graduate School of Arts and Sciences<br />

of Georgetown University<br />

<strong>in</strong> partial fulfillment of the requirements for the<br />

degree of<br />

Master of Arts<br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>Communication</strong>, <strong>Culture</strong> and Technology<br />

By<br />

Bethany L. Leickly, B.A.<br />

Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC<br />

April 30, 2004


INTERMEDIARIES IN INFORMATION ECONOMIES<br />

Bethany L. Leickly, B.A.<br />

Thesis Advisor: D. L<strong>in</strong>da Garcia, PhD<br />

Second Reader: Kathleen Wallman<br />

ii


To L<strong>in</strong>da Garcia, this thesis would not have been possible without you. I cannot thank<br />

you enough for your dedication. You cont<strong>in</strong>ue to <strong>in</strong>spire me.<br />

To Kathleen Wallman, thank you for encouragement and <strong>in</strong>sight.<br />

To Mom, Dad, Brandon and Eric, thank you for your constant love and support.<br />

To Larry, thank you for always be<strong>in</strong>g there for me and believ<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> me.<br />

iii


COPYRIGHT 2004 BY BETHANY L. LEICKLY<br />

ALL RIGHTS RESERVED<br />

iv


TABLE OF CONTENTS<br />

Chapter 1. Introduction........................................................................................1<br />

Chapter 2. <strong>Information</strong> and Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty: A Conceptual Framework ....................9<br />

Introduction........................................................................................9<br />

<strong>Information</strong> and its role <strong>in</strong> the economy ...........................................10<br />

i. <strong>Information</strong> def<strong>in</strong>ed.................................................................10<br />

ii. <strong>Information</strong>: an uncerta<strong>in</strong> commodity?....................................13<br />

iii. <strong>Information</strong> asymmetry..........................................................14<br />

Technology and <strong>in</strong>formation.............................................................16<br />

Contend<strong>in</strong>g with uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty .............................................................18<br />

i. Agency theory ..........................................................................19<br />

ii. Transaction cost theory...........................................................20<br />

Intermediation ..................................................................................24<br />

Conclusion........................................................................................27<br />

Chapter 3. Historical Analysis ............................................................................29<br />

Introduction......................................................................................29<br />

The traditional market.......................................................................30<br />

The market expands..........................................................................32<br />

Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>in</strong> the Industrial Revolution ...........................................35<br />

Conclusion........................................................................................41<br />

Chapter 4. Technology and Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong> the Digital Age ..............................45<br />

Introduction......................................................................................45<br />

Digital technology advances..............................................................46<br />

New uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties .............................................................................49<br />

i. <strong>Information</strong> overload ...............................................................50<br />

ii. <strong>Information</strong> asymmetry...........................................................50<br />

iii. Technology ............................................................................51<br />

iv. Onl<strong>in</strong>e strategy .......................................................................51<br />

v. Mass customization.................................................................52<br />

v


vi. Asset specificity and networked firms.....................................53<br />

vii. <strong>Information</strong> commodities......................................................53<br />

viii. Personal <strong>in</strong>formation collection............................................54<br />

ix. Privacy ...................................................................................55<br />

x. Trust .......................................................................................58<br />

New roles for <strong>in</strong>termediaries .............................................................59<br />

i. Rules for success ......................................................................61<br />

Conclusion........................................................................................63<br />

Chapter 5. Infomediaries <strong>in</strong> e-Commerce: Case Studies.....................................65<br />

Introduction......................................................................................65<br />

Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s <strong>in</strong>fomediary model ..............................................66<br />

Infomediaries <strong>in</strong> practice...................................................................68<br />

i. Lumeria....................................................................................69<br />

ii. AllAdvantage...........................................................................70<br />

iii. Firefly/Passport .....................................................................72<br />

Shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs of <strong>in</strong>fomediaries..........................................................73<br />

Alternatives.......................................................................................77<br />

i. eBay .........................................................................................78<br />

ii. Amazon.com...........................................................................81<br />

Conclusion........................................................................................83<br />

Chapter 6. Conclusion........................................................................................87<br />

Suggested areas of research ...............................................................93<br />

References..............................................................................................................95<br />

vi


Chapter 1. Introduction<br />

<strong>Information</strong> is an essential component of any market. In all transactions, buyers<br />

and sellers must exchange <strong>in</strong>formation about the product, price, and settlement. Hence,<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals must acquire <strong>in</strong>formation to make <strong>in</strong>formed decisions <strong>in</strong> the purchase of both<br />

goods and services (K<strong>in</strong>gma, 2001). Only recently has the economy has been labeled an<br />

“<strong>in</strong>formation economy;” yet the market has always relied on the exchange of <strong>in</strong>formation.<br />

In spite of the importance of <strong>in</strong>formation, neoclassical economics largely ignores<br />

its role (Wolpert & Wolpert, 1986). The neoclassical model assumes that market<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation is perfect, and thus transaction costs are low. In reality, perfect <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

is impossible. Instead, actors have <strong>in</strong>sufficient and asymmetric <strong>in</strong>formation, so they must<br />

make decisions based on bounded rationality. This lack of perfect <strong>in</strong>formation results <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>creased transaction costs for buyers and sellers alike.<br />

Br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g buyers and sellers together, <strong>in</strong>termediaries have traditionally served to<br />

reduce these <strong>in</strong>formation-related transaction costs. An <strong>in</strong>termediary works as an<br />

economic agent who helps buyers and sellers f<strong>in</strong>d each other and execute a transaction.<br />

Equally important, they help to sort, classify, and distribute market <strong>in</strong>formation and<br />

goods. Not surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, the role of <strong>in</strong>termediaries has cont<strong>in</strong>ued to grow, and become<br />

more specialized, as advances <strong>in</strong> communication and transportation technologies <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

the size and complexity of the marketplace (Beniger, 1986; Garcia, 2002; M. D. Smith,<br />

Bailey, & Brynjolfsson, 2000; Spulber, 1998).<br />

1


Today, however, further advances <strong>in</strong> technology and communication threaten the<br />

role of the traditional <strong>in</strong>termediary. Based on the Internet, these technologies transform<br />

the locale of bus<strong>in</strong>ess transactions from the traditional marketplace to cyberspace.<br />

Although the Internet exponentially expands the size and scope of the market for<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers, it also gives them direct access to each other. Thus, for<br />

example, us<strong>in</strong>g the Internet, bus<strong>in</strong>esses can advertise and market directly to customers,<br />

while consumers can employ web technology to seek out the bus<strong>in</strong>esses that they want.<br />

These technological capabilities facilitate “dis<strong>in</strong>termediation,” or the elim<strong>in</strong>ation of the<br />

middleman <strong>in</strong> the value cha<strong>in</strong>.<br />

This chang<strong>in</strong>g paradigm of bus<strong>in</strong>ess processes is shift<strong>in</strong>g the focus on the Internet<br />

from traditional goods to <strong>in</strong>formation goods and services, usher<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the true<br />

“<strong>in</strong>formation economy”. The <strong>in</strong>frastructure of the Internet adds value to <strong>in</strong>formation by<br />

enhanc<strong>in</strong>g the ability to store, retrieve, filter, repackage, and distribute it (C. Shapiro &<br />

Varian, 1998). As a result, <strong>in</strong>formation can more easily be commodified—that is to say,<br />

bought and sold for a price <strong>in</strong> the marketplace. Us<strong>in</strong>g the Internet, for example,<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>esses can now access vast amounts of data from their customers, such as<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation about credit cards, bank accounts, purchases, demographics and other<br />

personal data (Larson, 1992). Even more important, bus<strong>in</strong>esses now have an <strong>in</strong>centive to<br />

collect this customer data—they can sell it, trade it and use it for direct market<strong>in</strong>g. By<br />

controll<strong>in</strong>g consumer <strong>in</strong>formation, bus<strong>in</strong>esses can maximize profits and reduce transaction<br />

2


costs. Thus, <strong>in</strong>formation commodities <strong>in</strong>clude not only <strong>in</strong>tangible goods, but also<br />

commercial uses of personal <strong>in</strong>formation.<br />

Because of the enhanced value of <strong>in</strong>formation, there is, however, a greater<br />

potential for personal <strong>in</strong>formation to be misused by bus<strong>in</strong>esses. For, <strong>in</strong> capitaliz<strong>in</strong>g on<br />

such consumer <strong>in</strong>formation, bus<strong>in</strong>esses subject consumers to a loss of property and<br />

privacy rights (Frost, Dec. 1980). Moreover, consumers have no control over how their<br />

personal <strong>in</strong>formation might be used or shared—to their detriment—with others. Not<br />

surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, there has been a grow<strong>in</strong>g concern about personal privacy and the need to<br />

impose stricter controls over bus<strong>in</strong>esses’ use of personal <strong>in</strong>formation (Cavoukian &<br />

Tapscott, 1997).<br />

Clearly, a balance must be achieved that gives consumers greater control of their<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation, while allow<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>esses to capitalize on recent technology advances. One<br />

way of resolv<strong>in</strong>g this tension is through a new k<strong>in</strong>d of <strong>in</strong>termediary. With this potential <strong>in</strong><br />

m<strong>in</strong>d, John Hagel III and Marc S<strong>in</strong>ger put forth a new concept <strong>in</strong> the late 1990s—the so-<br />

called “<strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>termediary”, or “<strong>in</strong>fomediary”. The <strong>in</strong>fomediary was <strong>in</strong>tended to<br />

help customers capture, manage and maximize the value of their private <strong>in</strong>formation.<br />

Specifically, Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger proposed that new bus<strong>in</strong>esses be established to act on<br />

behalf of consumers by negotiat<strong>in</strong>g how their personal <strong>in</strong>formation would be made<br />

available to bus<strong>in</strong>esses. Consequently, a relationship between the <strong>in</strong>fomediary, the<br />

3


consumer and the bus<strong>in</strong>ess would presumably be developed based on trust and<br />

transparency (Hagel & S<strong>in</strong>ger, 1999; Rosenblatt, July 1999).<br />

Although Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s idea was touted as the panacea, susta<strong>in</strong>able<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediaries have yet to materialize (Rosenblatt, July 1999). In 1999, several such<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries were founded to help consumers handle their personal <strong>in</strong>formation. These<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded Privaseek, Lumeria and AllAdvantage (Muller, 2000; Pomeroy, n.d.). The results<br />

have hardly been successful. By 2004, Privaseek was non-existent; the AllAdvantage<br />

website redirected users to a different website 1 ; and Lumeria’s website had been <strong>in</strong>active<br />

s<strong>in</strong>ce 2000 2 .<br />

The present dearth of <strong>in</strong>fomediaries suggests that Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s concept was<br />

flawed <strong>in</strong> some fundamental way. The failure of the <strong>in</strong>fomediary model raises a number<br />

of related questions. In particular, what accounts for the lack of both supply of and<br />

demand for <strong>in</strong>fomediaries <strong>in</strong> today’s <strong>in</strong>formation-based economy? Is it a function of the<br />

chang<strong>in</strong>g role of <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> the economy, the advent of <strong>in</strong>formation technology, new<br />

sources of transaction costs, or some comb<strong>in</strong>ation of these factors? Are there any<br />

circumstances under which an <strong>in</strong>termediary can succeed <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formation economy?<br />

Because new communications technologies provide a direct l<strong>in</strong>k between the<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess and the consumer, the traditional role of an <strong>in</strong>termediary may no longer be viable<br />

1 http://aia.plugus<strong>in</strong>4cash.com/<br />

2 http://www.lumeria.com/<br />

4


<strong>in</strong> the digital age. Historically, <strong>in</strong>termediaries found a niche <strong>in</strong> markets where transaction<br />

costs were high, and they served both the buyer and the seller <strong>in</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g these costs.<br />

The middleman worked on behalf of both the bus<strong>in</strong>ess and the consumer, negotiat<strong>in</strong>g a<br />

contract between them. As technology reduces transaction costs for both parties, thereby<br />

underm<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the role of the middleman, <strong>in</strong>termediaries must redef<strong>in</strong>e their role and f<strong>in</strong>d<br />

new ways to add value to bus<strong>in</strong>ess transactions.<br />

This thesis hypothesizes that the <strong>in</strong>fomediary model put forth by Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger<br />

failed because, <strong>in</strong> controll<strong>in</strong>g private <strong>in</strong>formation, it sought to provide support for the<br />

customer alone. In so do<strong>in</strong>g, the model failed to create enough <strong>in</strong>centives for bus<strong>in</strong>esses<br />

to buy <strong>in</strong>to the solution. As history shows, the middleman must benefit both the buyer<br />

and the seller, and the <strong>in</strong>fomediary failed to do this.<br />

A second hypothesis account<strong>in</strong>g for the failed model is that it did not adequately<br />

take <strong>in</strong>to account several key aspects of a networked economy. Most notably,<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediaries are subject to extremely high fixed costs, network effects, bandwagon<br />

effects and unravel<strong>in</strong>g. These factors made it difficult for <strong>in</strong>fomediaries to susta<strong>in</strong><br />

themselves <strong>in</strong> the digital marketplace.<br />

Furthermore, the <strong>in</strong>fomediary, <strong>in</strong> its effort to work on behalf of the customer to<br />

protect personal <strong>in</strong>formation and privacy, had to first ga<strong>in</strong> the confidence of the<br />

consumer. However, <strong>in</strong> the unstable environment follow<strong>in</strong>g the dot-com bust, the fate of<br />

the <strong>in</strong>fomediaries was highly uncerta<strong>in</strong>. Hence, consumers were wary to trust an<br />

5


<strong>in</strong>fomediary to control all of their personal <strong>in</strong>formation, not know<strong>in</strong>g if the company<br />

would prosper or fold.<br />

As a f<strong>in</strong>al hypothesis, this thesis suggests that there is a role for the <strong>in</strong>fomediary <strong>in</strong><br />

the <strong>in</strong>formation economy. For while communication and technology advances promote<br />

dis<strong>in</strong>termediation <strong>in</strong> some markets, there are <strong>in</strong>stances <strong>in</strong> which <strong>in</strong>termediaries can still<br />

add value to bus<strong>in</strong>ess transactions. However, <strong>in</strong>termediaries can only succeed as<br />

differentiated, specialized agents for commerce, not as watchdogs of consumer<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation and privacy. Thus, the benefit will come from the <strong>in</strong>termediary’s ability to<br />

reduce transaction costs by address<strong>in</strong>g the problems of the <strong>in</strong>formation overload<br />

associated with the <strong>in</strong>formation economy. The solutions to the problems of privacy and<br />

consumer <strong>in</strong>formation protection will require a new model for the relationship between<br />

customers and bus<strong>in</strong>ess--a model that relies on trust, social and legal contracts, <strong>in</strong>centives,<br />

and procedural fairness <strong>in</strong> handl<strong>in</strong>g personal <strong>in</strong>formation.<br />

To test these hypotheses, this thesis will proceed as follows. Chapter Two will<br />

conceptualize the role of <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> the economy and how it gives rise to transaction<br />

costs. In addition, it will describe and analyze the case of <strong>in</strong>formation impactedness and<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry, and how it affects economic activity and the relationships among<br />

economic actors. The chapter will then lay out the relationship between trust and<br />

transaction costs. F<strong>in</strong>ally, the chapter will def<strong>in</strong>e the role of <strong>in</strong>termediaries and their<br />

potential to reduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and transaction costs.<br />

6


Build<strong>in</strong>g on this theoretical framework, Chapter Three will look from an historical<br />

perspective at the role that <strong>in</strong>termediaries have played <strong>in</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs.<br />

Special attention will be given to the role that communication and technological advances<br />

have played both <strong>in</strong> expand<strong>in</strong>g markets and generat<strong>in</strong>g the need for the middleman <strong>in</strong><br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess. It will show how, under various circumstances, these technologies generated<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and hence different types of <strong>in</strong>termediary roles. Understand<strong>in</strong>g how these<br />

factors led to the chang<strong>in</strong>g role of the <strong>in</strong>termediary over time, we will be better able to<br />

anticipate the <strong>in</strong>termediary’s role <strong>in</strong> the networked economy.<br />

Turn<strong>in</strong>g to the present, Chapter Four will lay out and discuss the emerg<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation-related issues that bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers face <strong>in</strong> the digital age. The<br />

chapter will beg<strong>in</strong> with a brief characterization of today’s technology advances, and how<br />

they are likely to affect transaction costs <strong>in</strong> a general sense. Next, the chapter will look<br />

more specifically at the impact of new technologies on <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry, the<br />

potential for collect<strong>in</strong>g consumer <strong>in</strong>formation, privacy concerns and <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

overload. Hav<strong>in</strong>g identified the sources of digitally-related uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties and risks, it will<br />

suggest how <strong>in</strong>termediaries might play a useful role.<br />

Chapter Five will analyze the role that <strong>in</strong>termediaries presently play <strong>in</strong> e-commerce<br />

and the <strong>in</strong>formation economy. In particular, it will seek to determ<strong>in</strong>e why some<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries have failed to capture the necessary critical mass of users, while others have<br />

successfully stepped <strong>in</strong> to deal with <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry and <strong>in</strong>formation overload. At<br />

7


the same time, it will identify and analyze under what circumstances bus<strong>in</strong>esses have<br />

successfully elim<strong>in</strong>ated the middleman from their value cha<strong>in</strong>.<br />

In conclusion, Chapter Six will summarize the lessons learned. Build<strong>in</strong>g on the<br />

discussions <strong>in</strong> the previous chapter, this chapter will discuss the likelihood that consumers<br />

and bus<strong>in</strong>esses will f<strong>in</strong>d an adequate <strong>in</strong>centive to support the role of an <strong>in</strong>termediary and<br />

the circumstances under which they might be most likely to do so.<br />

8


Chapter 2. <strong>Information</strong> and Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty: A Conceptual Framework<br />

Introduction<br />

To answer the question Are there any circumstances under which an <strong>in</strong>termediary can succeed<br />

<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formation economy?, the general function of an <strong>in</strong>termediary must be understood.<br />

Also, before exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the role that <strong>in</strong>termediaries play <strong>in</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong> the<br />

digital age, it is necessary to lay out a conceptual framework, focus<strong>in</strong>g on uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties of<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> any economic system. Only by understand<strong>in</strong>g the fundamental role that<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation plays <strong>in</strong> the economy can we exam<strong>in</strong>e the factors that give rise to the role of<br />

the <strong>in</strong>termediary. This conceptualization will serve as a basis for the follow<strong>in</strong>g chapters, <strong>in</strong><br />

which the <strong>in</strong>termediary is analyzed <strong>in</strong> both historical and present day markets.<br />

Furthermore, by understand<strong>in</strong>g the general pr<strong>in</strong>ciples underly<strong>in</strong>g the function of the<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediary, the viability of the “<strong>in</strong>fomediary” model <strong>in</strong> the digital age can be analyzed.<br />

To this end, the chapter first def<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong>formation and its role <strong>in</strong> the economy,<br />

focus<strong>in</strong>g on the uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties to which <strong>in</strong>formation gives rise. Particular emphasis is given<br />

to <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry and the commodification of <strong>in</strong>formation. Secondly, the<br />

chapter identifies how technologies serve as catalysts for chang<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties related to<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation. Consider<strong>in</strong>g all these factors, the next section presents two theories—agency<br />

theory and transaction cost theory—each of which seek to expla<strong>in</strong> the conditions of<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty that are <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> any economy. Next, the chapter def<strong>in</strong>es the role of<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries, how they function, and how they reduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and transaction costs.<br />

9


Based on this analysis, this chapter identifies the key conditions under which<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries can be viable economic actors.<br />

<strong>Information</strong> and its role <strong>in</strong> the economy<br />

i. <strong>Information</strong> def<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

<strong>Information</strong> is a “fuzzy” concept, which has become the subject of economic<br />

analysis only <strong>in</strong> the past 100 years (Rose, 1999, 6). Economists differ <strong>in</strong> their def<strong>in</strong>itions<br />

of <strong>in</strong>formation. 3 However, given the focus of this thesis on the role of <strong>in</strong>termediaries, a<br />

def<strong>in</strong>ition that relates to uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is most appropriate. Thus for the purpose of this<br />

thesis, the follow<strong>in</strong>g def<strong>in</strong>ition will take precedence. <strong>Information</strong> is that which can be<br />

exploited to reduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>in</strong> decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g (Rose, 1999, 10). Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is<br />

def<strong>in</strong>ed as “the dispersion of <strong>in</strong>dividuals’ subjective probability (or belief) distributions<br />

over possible states of the world,” (Hirshleifer, 1973, 31). Thus, <strong>in</strong>formation is a message<br />

that an <strong>in</strong>dividual receives that reduces uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>in</strong> his or her environment. In<br />

economics, this refers to the knowledge of prices, agents, and supply and demand of<br />

products.<br />

3 Some def<strong>in</strong>itions of <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>clude “knowledge is power,” (Stigler, 1971, 61); “the negative measure<br />

of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty…and an economically <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g category of goods,” (Arrow, 1984, 138); and “anyth<strong>in</strong>g that<br />

can be digitized,” (C. Shapiro & Varian, 1998, 3).<br />

10


In some cases, uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty also creates a market for <strong>in</strong>formation. When agents are<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong> about future events—the quality of products, or the honesty of others—they<br />

look to purchase <strong>in</strong>formation to reduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty (K<strong>in</strong>gma, 2001). In this sense,<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation decreases the risk <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> complex transactions. Risk is “the potential for<br />

loss when uncerta<strong>in</strong> future events may cause economic harm,” (K<strong>in</strong>gma, 2001, 89). To<br />

understand how agents can exploit <strong>in</strong>formation, it is first necessary to operationalize these<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties.<br />

All <strong>in</strong>formation can be described by common properties. For one, <strong>in</strong>formation is<br />

an <strong>in</strong>tangible resource and an immaterial good (Rose, 1999). Second, <strong>in</strong>formation is a<br />

highly fungible resource (Sampler, 1998). In this sense, it can be exchanged or<br />

<strong>in</strong>terchanged with other <strong>in</strong>formation. Yet, <strong>in</strong>formation varies <strong>in</strong> its degree of fungibility or<br />

alternative uses (Sampler, 1998). 4 Thus, the nature and value of <strong>in</strong>formation change<br />

accord<strong>in</strong>g to its use. In addition, the production of <strong>in</strong>formation goods <strong>in</strong>volves high fixed<br />

costs and low marg<strong>in</strong>al costs (C. Shapiro & Varian, 1998). There are also high sunk costs<br />

<strong>in</strong> creat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation, but it is relatively cheap to replicate. Thus, “<strong>in</strong>formation is costly<br />

to produce but cheap to reproduce,” (C. Shapiro & Varian, 1998, 3). Unlike tangible<br />

4 Sampler gives an example of us<strong>in</strong>g customer demographic data to expla<strong>in</strong> the vary<strong>in</strong>g fungibility of<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation: “customer demographic data may be highly applicable to a wide variety of consumer goods<br />

firms, but <strong>in</strong>formation regard<strong>in</strong>g the quantity of a particular product…would be less fungible, i.e., it would<br />

have fewer alternative uses or be applicable <strong>in</strong> fewer situations,” (Sampler, 1998, 346).<br />

11


goods, <strong>in</strong>formation is subject to perfectly <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g returns. Once the <strong>in</strong>itial <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

is made, <strong>in</strong>formation can be reused at no additional cost. Likewise, <strong>in</strong>formation can be<br />

replicated at zero cost and without limit, and it will never wear out or deteriorate, unlike<br />

tangible goods. However, <strong>in</strong>formation may become obsolete or untrue with time, and its<br />

value may decrease the more it is replicated (Evans & Wurster, 2000).<br />

<strong>Information</strong> is a non-exclusive good, a feature that generates uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong><br />

markets where <strong>in</strong>formation is sold (K<strong>in</strong>gma, 2001, 7). For example, when <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

transfers between a producer and user, usually only a copy of the <strong>in</strong>formation is sold. The<br />

producer keeps the actual <strong>in</strong>formation. Likewise, the seller reta<strong>in</strong>s the <strong>in</strong>formation even<br />

once it is sold. Thus that same piece of <strong>in</strong>formation can be enjoyed by more than one<br />

consumer simultaneously (K<strong>in</strong>gma, 2001, 7). The buyer can also copy and distribute the<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation without the seller’s knowledge. Thus, the seller risks loss of compensation<br />

for the <strong>in</strong>formation’s future uses. The non-exclusive nature of <strong>in</strong>formation also <strong>in</strong>duces a<br />

disclosure problem for agents sell<strong>in</strong>g it, because its use by one agent may reveal the<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation to others. Moreover, when agents hesitate to reveal <strong>in</strong>formation additional<br />

market uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is created. As a result, agents are likely to under-<strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> the<br />

production of knowledge and <strong>in</strong>formation (Rose, 1999, 18).<br />

Market uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties also arise because the true value of <strong>in</strong>formation cannot be<br />

predicted ex ante (Rose, 1999, 18-19). More specifically, a consumer cannot know the<br />

value and worth of a piece of <strong>in</strong>formation before buy<strong>in</strong>g it. If the seller exhibits the<br />

12


<strong>in</strong>formation before sell<strong>in</strong>g it, it has <strong>in</strong> effect been given away. Thus, the buyer is at risk,<br />

never know<strong>in</strong>g the exact nature of the <strong>in</strong>formation be<strong>in</strong>g purchased. As <strong>in</strong> the case of<br />

non-exclusivities, these uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties may also lead to an underdeveloped market for<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation.<br />

Given these unique characteristics, <strong>in</strong>formation does not easily fit <strong>in</strong> the traditional<br />

neoclassical economic model. As Boisot has po<strong>in</strong>ted out, “Neoclassical economics has<br />

addressed the problem of <strong>in</strong>formation goods somewhat schizophrenically,” (Boisot, 1998,<br />

76). On one hand, economic theory treats <strong>in</strong>formation as a free good that is not subject<br />

to trad<strong>in</strong>g and is <strong>in</strong>stantaneously available to all economic agents. In this respect, it<br />

functions as a support to exchange and “to foster the perfect foresight so essential to<br />

efficient markets,” (Boisot, 1998, 76). Conversely, neoclassical economics also treats<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation as a good that, through artificial means, can be made subject to the same<br />

scrut<strong>in</strong>y of physical goods and thus also to the normal rules of trad<strong>in</strong>g. In the first case,<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation has utility, but because it is <strong>in</strong> abundance, it has no value. In the second case,<br />

it has both utility and scarcity, and therefore has value (Boisot, 1998).<br />

ii. <strong>Information</strong>: an uncerta<strong>in</strong> commodity?<br />

Because <strong>in</strong>formation is different from tangible goods, questions arise as to<br />

whether it can function as a true commodity <strong>in</strong> the marketplace. An economic<br />

commodity is an item that can be traded for a price (Allen, 1990, 268). To be classified as<br />

a commodity, goods must directly or <strong>in</strong>directly satisfy a human need, they must be limited,<br />

13


and their production must compete with other commodities for scarce resources (Rose,<br />

1999, 36). Furthermore, buyers and sellers must be able to judge whether the properties of<br />

a good satisfies their needs. As well, they must be secure <strong>in</strong> the property rights of the<br />

commodity, so they can use the resource, reta<strong>in</strong> the returns, alter the resource, and<br />

alienate the resource (Tietzel, 1981, as cited by Rose, 1999, 37). Lastly, the commodities<br />

must possess an exchange value (Rose, 1999, 36).<br />

Accord<strong>in</strong>g to these criteria, <strong>in</strong>formation possesses some characteristics of a<br />

commodity. The fit, however, is problematic, which is the source of additional market<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties. As we have seen, <strong>in</strong>formation is non-rivalrous <strong>in</strong>sofar as the use of<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation by one person does not exclude its use by others. Moreover, because of its<br />

low marg<strong>in</strong>al costs, it does not compete for scarce resources, and it is easily reproduced.<br />

Equally problematic, ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g property rights <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>tangible resources, such as<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation, is very difficult because such commodities are non-exclusive. Thus, the<br />

question as to who owns the <strong>in</strong>formation arises. Both the buyer and the seller can<br />

simultaneously possess the <strong>in</strong>formation, and use it as they chose.<br />

iii. <strong>Information</strong> asymmetry<br />

The problematic nature of <strong>in</strong>formation as a commodity exacerbates the problems<br />

of <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry and imperfect <strong>in</strong>formation, which are features of any economy.<br />

Asymmetries are associated with the uneven distribution of <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> the<br />

marketplace (Phlips, 1988, 4). When <strong>in</strong>formation is commoditized and exchanged for<br />

14


value <strong>in</strong> the marketplace, certa<strong>in</strong> agents will <strong>in</strong>variably have more <strong>in</strong>formation than other<br />

agents. For example, a buyer may have more complete <strong>in</strong>formation than the seller, and<br />

visa versa.<br />

<strong>Information</strong> asymmetries may occur for a number of reasons. For example, <strong>in</strong><br />

some markets, <strong>in</strong>formation is available but producers are not will<strong>in</strong>g to reveal it to<br />

consumers. A producer will get a better price if he can hide <strong>in</strong>formation from consumers.<br />

These uniformed or mis<strong>in</strong>formed consumers make poor decisions about a product’s<br />

value. Thus, they are reluctant to buy goods and services, thereby reduc<strong>in</strong>g the number of<br />

transactions <strong>in</strong> a market (K<strong>in</strong>gma, 2001).<br />

<strong>Information</strong> asymmetry also causes <strong>in</strong>formation impactedness. Def<strong>in</strong>ed by Oliver<br />

Williamson, <strong>in</strong>formation impactedness is the condition that occurs when the buyer and<br />

the seller have knowledge of different and essentially private <strong>in</strong>formation when they take<br />

part <strong>in</strong> complex contract<strong>in</strong>g (Williamson, 1985, 51). This condition is costly to overcome<br />

and gives rise to a trad<strong>in</strong>g hazard, occasionally result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> market failure (Akerlof, 1970,<br />

cited by Williamson, 1985, 212).<br />

Asymmetrical <strong>in</strong>formation negatively affects market transactions. At a m<strong>in</strong>imum,<br />

asymmetries make the market operate less efficiently <strong>in</strong>sofar as prices will not represent<br />

real costs and benefits (K<strong>in</strong>gma, 2001, 92). In the worse case, if parties are discouraged<br />

from transact<strong>in</strong>g, asymmetries can underm<strong>in</strong>e the market all together. Economist George<br />

Akerlof (1970) provides the classic example of such a case <strong>in</strong> his article, “The Market for<br />

15


Lemons.” As he describes, the seller has an <strong>in</strong>centive to misrepresent the car’s quality,<br />

and the buyer has little <strong>in</strong>centive to believe what the seller says. This uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty prevents<br />

transactions between high quality buyers and sellers (Akerlof, 1970).<br />

To overcome the problems of imperfect <strong>in</strong>formation and <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry,<br />

a third party can mediate between the buyer and the seller. One solution is the creation of<br />

an agent who will act <strong>in</strong> both the user’s and producer’s <strong>in</strong>terest (Ste<strong>in</strong>mueller, 1992). “An<br />

agent’s <strong>in</strong>centives to compromise the producer’s <strong>in</strong>formation by reveal<strong>in</strong>g it to [the] user<br />

can be offset by contracts and the <strong>in</strong>centives to cont<strong>in</strong>ue to ga<strong>in</strong> economic returns<br />

through repeat deal<strong>in</strong>g with producers,” (Ste<strong>in</strong>mueller, 1992, 191). Repeat deal<strong>in</strong>g and<br />

reputation effects would discourage misrepresentation of <strong>in</strong>formation to the buyer. This<br />

solution aligns <strong>in</strong>centives between producers and users (Ste<strong>in</strong>mueller, 1992, 191). Thus, a<br />

third party –an <strong>in</strong>termediary—reduces <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry.<br />

Technology and <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

Technology is <strong>in</strong>tr<strong>in</strong>sically tied to <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> an economy because technology<br />

advances affect how <strong>in</strong>formation is produced and transmitted. In the past, major<br />

technological advances improved communication techniques, which affected both the use<br />

of <strong>in</strong>formation and physical transport. “<strong>Information</strong> technologies related to<br />

communication and transports have a common property, namely to be very general<br />

(generic) <strong>in</strong> application, and contribut<strong>in</strong>g to the coord<strong>in</strong>ation and filter<strong>in</strong>g processes of the<br />

16


economy…they exercise leverage effects on the entire economic system,” (Gunnar,<br />

Folster, L<strong>in</strong>dberg, Pousette, & Taymaz, 1990, 18).<br />

Examples of technologies that have changed the distribution and control of<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>clude the pr<strong>in</strong>ted word, the steam eng<strong>in</strong>e, electricity, standardization,<br />

automobile transport, f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions, electronics based <strong>in</strong>formation technology, and<br />

general education. The pr<strong>in</strong>ted word was a “path-break<strong>in</strong>g production technology…(that)<br />

made it possible to pass on large volumes of knowledge <strong>in</strong> the abstract form of written<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation, a technology <strong>in</strong> itself,” (Gunnar et al., 1990, 19). With the advent of the<br />

pr<strong>in</strong>t<strong>in</strong>g press, barriers to the spread of <strong>in</strong>formation and knowledge were removed. The<br />

advances <strong>in</strong> transportation systems (notably steam eng<strong>in</strong>es and automobiles) also changed<br />

communication methods, <strong>in</strong>creased the transport of goods, and thus <strong>in</strong>creased the flow<br />

and exchange of <strong>in</strong>formation (Gunnar et al., 1990).<br />

As technology advances, certa<strong>in</strong> uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties are resolved. But, at the same time,<br />

new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties emerge as relationships are restructured (Garcia, 2002, 51).<br />

“Although…technologies can reduce transaction costs and improve economic<br />

performance, their usage will generate a whole range of new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties and transaction<br />

costs,”(Garcia, 2001, 3). To contend with these new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties, new means of control<br />

must be established. “For, while reduc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation-related costs <strong>in</strong> one part of the<br />

transaction cha<strong>in</strong>, these solutions serve simultaneously to generate new transaction costs<br />

elsewhere <strong>in</strong> the cha<strong>in</strong>, thereby creat<strong>in</strong>g anew the need for organizational and<br />

17


technological <strong>in</strong>novations,”(Garcia, 2002, 47). <strong>Information</strong> and communications<br />

technologies serve to control economic activities of production, distribution and<br />

consumption of goods and services (Beniger, 1986, 16). “A society’s ability to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><br />

control—at all levels from <strong>in</strong>terpersonal to <strong>in</strong>ternational relations—will be directly<br />

proportional to the development of its <strong>in</strong>formation technologies,”(Beniger, 1986, 8-9).<br />

Technology also affects the commoditization of <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> the economy.<br />

Because technologies offer <strong>in</strong>creased scope and reach <strong>in</strong> communication across the globe,<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation has a greater ability to be valued and exchanged <strong>in</strong> the marketplace. “The<br />

<strong>in</strong>creased availability and capacity of communication networks stresses the basic<br />

characteristics of <strong>in</strong>terdependence, <strong>in</strong>appropriablilty and externality of <strong>in</strong>formation as a<br />

commodity. At the same time it makes <strong>in</strong>formation an evergrow<strong>in</strong>g strategic <strong>in</strong>put <strong>in</strong><br />

decision mak<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong> production and consumption,” (Stiglitz, 1989, 198). Thus,<br />

technology <strong>in</strong>creases both the flow and value of <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> an economic system.<br />

Contend<strong>in</strong>g with uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty<br />

Neoclassical economics fails to take <strong>in</strong>to consideration the uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty of<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation, requir<strong>in</strong>g alternate theories to expla<strong>in</strong> the organization of markets. In this<br />

section, two of these theories are exam<strong>in</strong>ed: agency theory and transaction cost theory.<br />

Both offer explanations of and solutions for deal<strong>in</strong>g with uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, and thus help to<br />

expla<strong>in</strong> the role of the <strong>in</strong>termediary.<br />

18


i. Agency theory<br />

One relatively new theory that accounts for uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is agency theory. This<br />

theory, first developed <strong>in</strong> 1976, exam<strong>in</strong>es the contractual relationships <strong>in</strong> an organization<br />

(Karake-Shalhoub, 2002, 103). Agency theory assumes that human be<strong>in</strong>gs are rational,<br />

risk-averse, and motivated by self <strong>in</strong>terest (Karake-Shalhoub, 2002, 10). The theory aims<br />

to develop efficient organizational and contractual structures that can overcome problems<br />

of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty aris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> economic relationships. The ma<strong>in</strong> sources of these problems are<br />

the asymmetric distribution of <strong>in</strong>formation between actors, and uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty about the<br />

future states of the environment and actions taken by the agents (Rose, 1999, 27).<br />

In agency theory, there is a def<strong>in</strong>ed relationship between the “pr<strong>in</strong>cipal” and the<br />

“agent.” The agent (provider of the service) acts on behalf of the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal (user of the<br />

service). <strong>Information</strong> asymmetry affects the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal-agent relationship. Because both<br />

the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal and the agent are <strong>in</strong>dividuals who act <strong>in</strong> their own self-<strong>in</strong>terest, a conflict can<br />

occur when both parties attempt to maximize their <strong>in</strong>dividual self-<strong>in</strong>terest (Karake-<br />

Shalhoub, 2002, 105). Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty occurs when the agent’s action is not directly<br />

observable by the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal (Rose, 1999, 27). Without the ability to monitor the agent, the<br />

pr<strong>in</strong>cipal may assume that the agent is hid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation, which is a problem of moral<br />

hazard.<br />

Agency costs <strong>in</strong>cur from uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>cipal-agent relationships. Agency costs<br />

are the losses result<strong>in</strong>g from imperfect <strong>in</strong>formation, and they can result directly from the<br />

19


conflict between agent and pr<strong>in</strong>cipal. Moreover, agency costs can reduce the value of an<br />

organization. Thus, agency theory sets out to expla<strong>in</strong> how to best coord<strong>in</strong>ate relationships<br />

to reduce these costs (Karake-Shalhoub, 2002, 109).<br />

Agency theory offers solutions to help economic actors reduce agency costs and<br />

mitigate problems of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, moral hazard and adverse selection <strong>in</strong> the market. For<br />

example, signal<strong>in</strong>g, which reveals private <strong>in</strong>formation to the buyer, prevents adverse<br />

selection. Risk shar<strong>in</strong>g--where<strong>in</strong> the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal bears a portion of the risk to m<strong>in</strong>imize<br />

opportunism--can overcome the problem of moral hazard. Furthermore, uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty can<br />

be dim<strong>in</strong>ished by us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>centive schemes and control mechanisms <strong>in</strong> contracts (Karake-<br />

Shalhoub, 2002).<br />

ii. Transaction cost theory<br />

Another valuable theory for contend<strong>in</strong>g with uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is transaction cost<br />

theory. Transaction cost theory orig<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> the early twentieth century, and, like agency<br />

theory, it only recently came <strong>in</strong>to focus <strong>in</strong> economics. Transaction cost theory is<br />

concerned with how firms might best be organized to reduce <strong>in</strong>formation related costs.<br />

Transaction costs, as orig<strong>in</strong>ally def<strong>in</strong>ed by Ronald Coase <strong>in</strong> 1937 <strong>in</strong> his article “The Nature<br />

of the Firm,” add <strong>in</strong>efficiencies to the market (Coase, 1937, 390). Both Kenneth Arrow<br />

and Oliver Williamson played a sem<strong>in</strong>al role <strong>in</strong> expand<strong>in</strong>g on Coase’s postulations <strong>in</strong> the<br />

1970’s and 1980’s. Williamson def<strong>in</strong>es transaction costs as the “costs of runn<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

economic system,”(Williamson, 1985, 18).<br />

20


Transaction costs add to the price of a good or service, and <strong>in</strong>volve search costs,<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation costs, barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g costs, decision costs, polic<strong>in</strong>g costs and enforcement costs<br />

(Downes & Mui, 1998). In bus<strong>in</strong>ess transactions, transaction costs also <strong>in</strong>clude the<br />

negotiat<strong>in</strong>g, monitor<strong>in</strong>g and enforcement costs associated with the transfer of goods and<br />

services between the firm and the customer (G. R. Jones & Butler, 1988, 204).<br />

Transaction costs can apply to both the firm and the consumer, yet it is often the<br />

consumer that faces higher transaction costs, lead<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry <strong>in</strong> the<br />

market. Economic agents seek to reduce transaction costs, mak<strong>in</strong>g the market more<br />

efficient (Downes and Mui, 1998, 38).<br />

Transaction cost economics characterizes economic agents as hav<strong>in</strong>g several<br />

determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g features: bounded rationality, opportunism, and asset specificity (Williamson,<br />

1985, 30). Agents are subject to bounded rationality when mak<strong>in</strong>g decisions, “whence<br />

behavior is <strong>in</strong>tendedly rational, but only limitedly so,” (Simon, 1961, as cited by<br />

Williamson, 1985, 30). In this respect, transaction cost economics differs from agency<br />

theory, which assumes that economic agents are rational. In transaction cost economics,<br />

environmental and social factors limit an agent’s rationality.<br />

Opportunism often <strong>in</strong>volves blatant and subtle forms of deceit (Williamson, 1985,<br />

47). This refers to the <strong>in</strong>complete or distorted disclosure of <strong>in</strong>formation, especially the<br />

effort to mislead, distort, disguise, obfuscate, or otherwise confuse other agents<br />

(Williamson, 1985, 47). Opportunism is responsible for conditions of <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

21


asymmetry and uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, which, accord<strong>in</strong>g to Williamson, “vastly complicates problems<br />

of economic organization,” (Williamson, 1985, 48).<br />

The most critical element <strong>in</strong> transaction cost economics is asset specificity<br />

(Williamson, 1985, 30). Transactions that are supported by <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> transaction-<br />

specific assets experience “lock-<strong>in</strong>” effects (Williamson, 1985, 53). Assets that are specific<br />

to the transaction <strong>in</strong>clude cost advantage, such as a unique location or learn<strong>in</strong>g, or task-<br />

specific labor skills (Williamson, 1985, 54). There are four types of asset specificity: site,<br />

physical, human asset, and dedicated assets (Williamson, 1985, 55). 5<br />

Transaction cost economics thus seeks to expla<strong>in</strong> how uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong> the market<br />

might be reduced. Williamson proposes that an agent should “organize transactions so as<br />

to economize on bounded rationality while simultaneously safeguard<strong>in</strong>g them aga<strong>in</strong>st the<br />

hazards of opportunism,”(1985, 32). Williamson also argues that uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty would<br />

disappear if <strong>in</strong>dividuals were either fully open and honest <strong>in</strong> their efforts to realize<br />

5 Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Williamson, “asset specificity refers to durable <strong>in</strong>vestments that are undertaken <strong>in</strong> support of<br />

particular transactions, the opportunity cost of which <strong>in</strong>vestments is much lower <strong>in</strong> best alternative uses or<br />

by alternative users should the orig<strong>in</strong>al transaction be prematurely term<strong>in</strong>ated, and the specific identity of the<br />

parties to a transaction pla<strong>in</strong>ly matters <strong>in</strong> these circumstances, which is to say that cont<strong>in</strong>uity of the<br />

relationship is valued, whence contractual and organization safeguards arise <strong>in</strong> support of transactions of<br />

this k<strong>in</strong>d, which safeguards are unneeded (would be the source of avoidable costs) for transactions of the<br />

more familiar neo-classical (nonspecific) variety,” (1985, 55).<br />

22


<strong>in</strong>dividual advantage, or if full subord<strong>in</strong>ation, self-denial, and obedience could be<br />

presumed <strong>in</strong> the transaction (Williamson, 1985, 49).<br />

Trust plays an important role <strong>in</strong> transaction cost economics. Karake-Shalhoub<br />

def<strong>in</strong>es trust as “a social lubricant that allows consumers to transact with merchants who<br />

are not part of their immediate network,” (2002, 38). By plac<strong>in</strong>g trust <strong>in</strong> a merchant, the<br />

consumer alleviates the perception of risk <strong>in</strong> a transaction. High levels of perceived risk<br />

correspond with a high level of trust needed to execute a transaction. Thus, “when risk is<br />

present, trust is needed to make transactions possible,” (Karake-Shalhoub, 2002, 38).<br />

Distrust is an uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty that <strong>in</strong>creases transaction costs. When opportunism is<br />

present, trustworth<strong>in</strong>ess is rarely transparent (Williamson, 1985). Relationships are easily<br />

<strong>in</strong>vaded and exploited by agents who do not possess trustworth<strong>in</strong>ess. In other words, a<br />

lack of trust on the part of some actors decreases trustworth<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> all relationships,<br />

because an agent cannot be sure whom to trust. If one party trusts <strong>in</strong> another, it is mak<strong>in</strong>g<br />

itself vulnerable to the other party’s behavior (Karake-Shalhoub, 2002). To overcome<br />

this, agents must make concessions to the effects of opportunism (Williamson, 1985).<br />

There are several ways to build trust <strong>in</strong> economic relationships. First, competence<br />

can be a source of trust <strong>in</strong> asymmetric relationships. Competence means that parties<br />

display a level of professionalism, that they have the capability to follow through on<br />

promises, that they can realistically judge a situation, and they have strong <strong>in</strong>terpersonal<br />

skills (Karake-Shalhoub, 2002, 31). Other factors for establish<strong>in</strong>g consumer trust <strong>in</strong> a<br />

23


seller organization are reputation and size (Karake-Shalhoub, 2002, 39). Reputation is the<br />

extent to which buyers believe that the sell<strong>in</strong>g organization is honest and concerned about<br />

its customers. “The better the seller’s reputation, the more the seller has presumably<br />

committed resources to build that reputation, the higher the penalty from violat<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

consumer’s trust, and hence the more trustworthy the seller is perceived to be,” (Karake-<br />

Shalhoub, 2002, 39). Size matters because a large organization signals to the consumer<br />

that the bus<strong>in</strong>ess has <strong>in</strong>vested significant resources <strong>in</strong> the organization. Thus, the<br />

organization stands to lose a great deal if it acts <strong>in</strong> an untrustworthy way. Thus, the larger<br />

the firm, the greater the perception that it is act<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the customer’s best <strong>in</strong>terest (Karake-<br />

Shalhoub, 2002).<br />

Aga<strong>in</strong>, George Akerloff’s market for lemons exemplifies the importance of trust <strong>in</strong><br />

transactions (1970). Trust plays a large role <strong>in</strong> the market for lemons. The presence of<br />

dishonest agents <strong>in</strong> the market who offer <strong>in</strong>ferior goods tend to drive the market out of<br />

existence, because <strong>in</strong>ferior products drive out the legitimate bus<strong>in</strong>ess (Akerlof, 1970).<br />

“The cost of dishonesty lies not only <strong>in</strong> the amount by which the purchaser is cheated; the<br />

cost also must <strong>in</strong>clude the loss <strong>in</strong>curred from driv<strong>in</strong>g legitimate bus<strong>in</strong>ess out of existence,”<br />

(Akerlof, 1970, 495).<br />

Intermediation<br />

Hav<strong>in</strong>g presented two theories to expla<strong>in</strong> uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry<br />

<strong>in</strong> a market, several questions are raised: what role do <strong>in</strong>termediaries play <strong>in</strong> this framework? Can<br />

24


<strong>in</strong>termediaries step <strong>in</strong> to reduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties? Intermediation is a possible solution to the<br />

problems of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>in</strong> the economy. An <strong>in</strong>termediary steps <strong>in</strong> to overcome<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry, <strong>in</strong>formation impactedness, distrust, and high transaction costs<br />

associated with <strong>in</strong>formation (Rose, 1999). An <strong>in</strong>termediary functions by seek<strong>in</strong>g out<br />

suppliers, f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g and encourag<strong>in</strong>g buyers, select<strong>in</strong>g the buy and sell prices, def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the<br />

terms of transactions, manag<strong>in</strong>g the payments and keep<strong>in</strong>g records of transactions, and<br />

hold<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>ventories to provide liquidity or availability of goods and services (Spulber,<br />

1996). <strong>Intermediaries</strong> provide utility by <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the chances of a successful match<br />

between buyers and sellers, thus the need for an <strong>in</strong>termediary will come about because of<br />

frictions <strong>in</strong> the market (Cosimano, 1996).<br />

<strong>Intermediaries</strong> relieve both agency costs and transaction costs. <strong>Intermediaries</strong><br />

emerge <strong>in</strong> markets where transaction costs are high. As Coase and William purport, firms<br />

are organized to m<strong>in</strong>imize the role of transaction costs (Coase, 1937; Williamson, 1985).<br />

Thus, the <strong>in</strong>termediary can be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as a firm that acts to reduce transaction costs<br />

(Cosimano, 1996). The <strong>in</strong>termediary can also be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as a mechanism for<br />

controll<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and shar<strong>in</strong>g risk to reduce agency costs.<br />

The roles available to an <strong>in</strong>termediary are determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the types of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties<br />

present <strong>in</strong> the market (Spulber, 1996). The occurrence of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is a prerequisite for<br />

the existence and the justification of <strong>in</strong>termediaries (Gumbel, 1985, as cited by Rose, 1999,<br />

58). In markets where uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is present, <strong>in</strong>termediaries coord<strong>in</strong>ate transactions with<br />

25


oker<strong>in</strong>g activities. When opportunism is present, <strong>in</strong>termediaries create market<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation and provide guarantees for quality. Likewise, when it is costly to observe the<br />

actions of agents, <strong>in</strong>termediaries provide monitor<strong>in</strong>g and contract<strong>in</strong>g support.<br />

There is someth<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>tr<strong>in</strong>sic <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>termediation which solves the problems of moral<br />

hazard and appropriability which tend to <strong>in</strong>hibit the production of <strong>in</strong>formation (Leland<br />

and Pyle, 1977, as cited by T. S. Campbell & Kracaw, 1980, 863). To elim<strong>in</strong>ate<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation asymmetries regard<strong>in</strong>g the qualities of assets, the market must perceive<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation to be reliable. Reliability can only be achieved with the resolution of any<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and moral hazards which <strong>in</strong>hibit the production of <strong>in</strong>formation or dim<strong>in</strong>ish its<br />

<strong>in</strong>tegrity (Leland and Pyle, 1977, as cited by T. S. Campbell & Kracaw, 1980, 879).<br />

<strong>Intermediaries</strong> also emerge as <strong>in</strong>formation producers because the production of<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation, the protection of confidentiality, the provision of transactions services, as<br />

well as other <strong>in</strong>termediary services, are naturally complementary activities (T. S. Campbell<br />

& Kracaw, 1980). The moral hazard problem is resolved when the <strong>in</strong>termediary has a<br />

large enough position <strong>in</strong> the market to be trustworthy. <strong>Intermediaries</strong> are profitable when<br />

they can jo<strong>in</strong>tly produce <strong>in</strong>formation and other services valued by <strong>in</strong>vestors. Thus,<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries do not emerge only when there are difficulties created by asymmetric and<br />

costly <strong>in</strong>formation. They can profitably emerge when they can jo<strong>in</strong>tly produce<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation as well as other products or services valued by buyers and seller (T. S.<br />

Campbell & Kracaw, 1980).<br />

26


The <strong>in</strong>sertion of an <strong>in</strong>termediary <strong>in</strong> the value cha<strong>in</strong> can have negative impacts <strong>in</strong><br />

certa<strong>in</strong> situations. “Intermediation <strong>in</strong>troduces a further step of transaction <strong>in</strong> the value<br />

cha<strong>in</strong> and therewith causes additional transaction costs. So <strong>in</strong>termediation can only be<br />

advantageous if the <strong>in</strong>crease of value added through <strong>in</strong>termediation overcompensates the<br />

transaction costs additionally <strong>in</strong>curred,” (Rose, 1999, 46). Thus, to be viable,<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries must add value to transactions.<br />

Conclusion<br />

An <strong>in</strong>termediary seeks to reduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties for agents <strong>in</strong> markets that manifest<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry and ris<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs. But the specific nature of these<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties changes with each successive generation. The <strong>in</strong>termediary functions by<br />

produc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation, decreas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry and reduc<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs.<br />

Thus, at any particular po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> time, the function of <strong>in</strong>termediaries will depend on<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry, <strong>in</strong>formation impactedness, the commodification of <strong>in</strong>formation,<br />

and transaction costs. It is clear that for an <strong>in</strong>termediary to succeed, it must add value for<br />

both the buyer and the seller. In any economy—the age of mercantilism, the Industrial<br />

Revolution, or the Digital Age—<strong>in</strong>termediaries emerge when uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties are present <strong>in</strong><br />

the market. As these uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties change, the role of the <strong>in</strong>termediary changes as well.<br />

With this conceptual framework laid out, further consideration can be given to the<br />

role of <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> history and <strong>in</strong> present markets. Hav<strong>in</strong>g identified the<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties that give rise to <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> an economy, the next step is to analyze<br />

27


how these factors affected the role of <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> historical markets, from the<br />

traditional town square market to the Industrial Revolution. What uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties and<br />

transaction costs <strong>in</strong> these markets gave rise to the first <strong>in</strong>termediaries? What roles did<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries play <strong>in</strong> these markets?<br />

28


Introduction<br />

Chapter 3. Historical Analysis<br />

To assess the need for <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> the digital age, it is first necessary to<br />

understand the role that they have played historically <strong>in</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs and<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty. By identify<strong>in</strong>g the factors that determ<strong>in</strong>ed the <strong>in</strong>termediary’s role <strong>in</strong> the past,<br />

we can consider how these might apply <strong>in</strong> a digitally networked economy. Likewise, how<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries’ responded previously to technological changes can help us anticipate how<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries might react to today’s rapidly chang<strong>in</strong>g digital environment. The follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

historical account builds on the conceptual framework laid out <strong>in</strong> the previous chapter.<br />

This chapter first describes the traditional market, when trade took place <strong>in</strong> the<br />

town square. The focus is on the role that <strong>in</strong>formation played <strong>in</strong> the exchange of tangible<br />

goods and how buyers and sellers contended with uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties. Secondly, the chapter<br />

looks at how communications and technological advances expanded these markets, and<br />

thus gave rise to the <strong>in</strong>termediary. Particular consideration is given to grow<strong>in</strong>g market<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties and how <strong>in</strong>termediaries stepped <strong>in</strong> to resolve them. The chapter then<br />

considers the Industrial Revolution, focus<strong>in</strong>g on the new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties to which the<br />

railroads, telegraph, and telephone gave rise. In keep<strong>in</strong>g with the previous chapter,<br />

transaction cost theory and agency theory provide the basis for expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g these new<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties. Build<strong>in</strong>g on this analysis, the chapter exam<strong>in</strong>es the chang<strong>in</strong>g role of the<br />

29


<strong>in</strong>termediary <strong>in</strong> this new context. In conclusion, the chapter discusses how <strong>in</strong>termediaries<br />

must re<strong>in</strong>vent their roles to rema<strong>in</strong> viable <strong>in</strong> new technological contexts.<br />

The traditional market<br />

Before the development of national markets supported and susta<strong>in</strong>ed by advanced<br />

transport and communications networks, economic exchanges took place <strong>in</strong> traditional<br />

town markets, where transactions were conf<strong>in</strong>ed to the local town square (Garcia, 2001).<br />

At these markets, buyers and sellers directly exchanged commodities such as food, gra<strong>in</strong>s,<br />

and wares; goods were sold immediately and on sight. Social life revolved around the<br />

market. “It was at the market that the townspeople met, made deals, quarreled, perhaps<br />

came to blows,”(Braudel, 1982b, 30).<br />

Transactions <strong>in</strong> the traditional market relied, therefore, on personal relationships.<br />

In this type of barter economy, the producer dealt directly with the consumer, so<br />

middlemen played little part <strong>in</strong> execut<strong>in</strong>g transactions. Economic roles, moreover, were<br />

somewhat diffuse; the producer also served as the retailer who sold his or her goods<br />

directly to consumers. Furthermore, where coord<strong>in</strong>ation beyond the immediate<br />

marketplace was required, family partnerships, rather than <strong>in</strong>termediaries, were employed<br />

(Beniger, 1986; Shaw, 1912).<br />

As discussed <strong>in</strong> chapter two, <strong>in</strong>formation exchange is <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> any economy.<br />

Thus, traditional markets relied on the exchange of <strong>in</strong>formation, even though most ga<strong>in</strong>s<br />

came from the exchange of tangible goods. In a traditional local market, the flow of<br />

30


<strong>in</strong>formation was very dense. Even <strong>in</strong> the case of distant trade, most communication took<br />

place by word of mouth; for the written word (letters, chronicles, and official documents)<br />

was limited <strong>in</strong> its usage and dissem<strong>in</strong>ation (Reyerson, 2002, 145).<br />

Producers depended on gett<strong>in</strong>g quality <strong>in</strong>formation. Retailers were ma<strong>in</strong>ly<br />

concerned with supply and demand <strong>in</strong> local and distant markets, wars, politics,<br />

import/export regulations, monetary changes, climate, and agricultural conditions. To<br />

help obta<strong>in</strong> this <strong>in</strong>formation, notaries, <strong>in</strong>nkeepers and brokers acted as simple<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries, discover<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess opportunities and br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g buyers and sellers<br />

together. Yet the role of these <strong>in</strong>termediaries was undeveloped, and they took little part <strong>in</strong><br />

market (Garcia, 2001; F. M. Jones, 1937; Reyerson, 2002).<br />

Transaction costs and agency costs, therefore, were relatively low <strong>in</strong> traditional<br />

markets. Proximity helped to reduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, as buyers and sellers knew one another.<br />

In the town market, and buyers could easily monitor the producer’s behavior, protect<strong>in</strong>g<br />

aga<strong>in</strong>st moral hazard. Tight-knit social relations deterred producers from act<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> self-<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest, and thus agency costs from adverse selection were negligible. Furthermore,<br />

because the market was conf<strong>in</strong>ed to a specific locale, search costs were also low, and<br />

opportunism was m<strong>in</strong>imal (Garcia, 2002).<br />

However, there were still some uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties. Because the market was limited <strong>in</strong><br />

scale and scope, and buyers and sellers were immobile, they had few options and there<br />

was little competition (Williamson, 1985, 95). Moreover, once buyers and sellers became<br />

31


l<strong>in</strong>ked <strong>in</strong> tight-knit social relationships, they could easily become locked <strong>in</strong>, generat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

greater opportunity for one party to take advantage of the other. Under such<br />

circumstances, the cost of seek<strong>in</strong>g alternatives could be very high.<br />

Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty also arose due to <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetries. Buyers and sellers faced<br />

the problem of seek<strong>in</strong>g out their options, and the lack of transportation and<br />

communications <strong>in</strong>frastructures made this difficult. As Geertz characterizes the<br />

traditional market, <strong>in</strong>formation was:<br />

...poor, scarce, maldistributed, <strong>in</strong>efficiently communicated, and <strong>in</strong>tensely valued.<br />

The level of ignorance about everyth<strong>in</strong>g from product quality and go<strong>in</strong>g prices to<br />

market possibilities and production costs (was) very high, and much of the way <strong>in</strong><br />

which the (market functioned) can be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as an attempt to reduce such<br />

ignorance for someone, <strong>in</strong>crease it for someone, or defend someone aga<strong>in</strong>st it.<br />

(Geertz, 1978, as cited by McMillan, 2002, 41)<br />

The <strong>in</strong>ability of pr<strong>in</strong>cipals to monitor agents generated uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty about product quality<br />

and market prices, <strong>in</strong>creased agency costs, moral hazard and <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry. Yet,<br />

rather than rely<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>in</strong>termediaries to solve problems of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and reduce<br />

transaction costs, people relied on trust and shared cultural norms (Garcia, 2001).<br />

The market expands<br />

In the 1600’s, improvements <strong>in</strong> transportation, especially shipp<strong>in</strong>g, led to an<br />

expansion of trade. As traditional markets were dislocated and circumvented, Europe<br />

developed a commercial economy (Braudel, 1982b). This <strong>in</strong>creased market gave rise to<br />

greater uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty. The result was a greater division of labor; merchants emerged to<br />

32


organize the market, and the producer’s role became more circumscribed and specialized.<br />

Instead of sell<strong>in</strong>g his own goods directly, producers sold their f<strong>in</strong>ished products to<br />

merchants who—act<strong>in</strong>g as middlemen—sold them to consumers. Thus, the merchant<br />

made his money by <strong>in</strong>curr<strong>in</strong>g the transaction costs that <strong>in</strong>creased along with the<br />

complexity and scope of trade (Reyerson, 2002; Shaw, 1912).<br />

Nonetheless, as trade expanded, new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties arose. Trust and shared<br />

cultural norms could no longer resolve problems of market uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, so <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

asymmetries between producers, merchants and consumers grew (Garcia, 2001, 5).<br />

Furthermore, the task of br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g buyers and sellers together became more problematic,<br />

especially <strong>in</strong> the late 1700s when commercially organized markets gave way to nationally<br />

organized markets. Merchant middlemen could no longer ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> control of the market,<br />

so, once aga<strong>in</strong>, new types of <strong>in</strong>termediaries stepped <strong>in</strong> to reduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties. In<br />

particular, <strong>in</strong>termediaries contended with ris<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs and reduced search and<br />

barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g costs, protect<strong>in</strong>g aga<strong>in</strong>st opportunism for buyers and sellers (Braudel, 1982b;<br />

Reyerson, 2002; W. D. Smith, 1984).<br />

Given the ever-<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g size of the American market, it is not surpris<strong>in</strong>g that<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries eventually came to flourish and prosper <strong>in</strong> the New World. At first,<br />

however, American producers contended with uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty by resist<strong>in</strong>g specialization.<br />

Primitive communication facilities rendered it difficult for merchants to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> control<br />

33


at great distances, so they diversified their <strong>in</strong>vestments and functions and reduced their<br />

risks (Beniger, 1986).<br />

The first American <strong>in</strong>termediaries specialized <strong>in</strong> agricultural trade, the<br />

predom<strong>in</strong>ant form of trade <strong>in</strong> the US until the mid-1800’s. To reduce the uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties<br />

associated with agricultural goods, <strong>in</strong>termediaries classified and graded them. As Beniger<br />

describes with respect to the cotton market:<br />

Because its value varied markedly accord<strong>in</strong>g to quality and grade, an error <strong>in</strong><br />

classification would either prove costly to a seller or land him <strong>in</strong> litigation. This<br />

problem of preprocess<strong>in</strong>g bales <strong>in</strong>to their essential market <strong>in</strong>formation came to be<br />

resolved by yet another specialized middleman and <strong>in</strong>formation worker: the cotton<br />

broker. In larger ports where trade volume permitted, <strong>in</strong>dividual brokers served as<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries between buyers and sellers, help<strong>in</strong>g them to f<strong>in</strong>d one another for a<br />

commission and to agree on a shipment’s quality and grade. (1986, 139-140)<br />

To trade <strong>in</strong> distant markets, bus<strong>in</strong>essmen and markets needed specialized<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation. Lack<strong>in</strong>g a high-quality communication <strong>in</strong>frastructure, American<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>essmen and farmers depended on a large cha<strong>in</strong> of middlemen to gather <strong>in</strong>formation.<br />

Thus, for example, commissioned middlemen stepped <strong>in</strong> to furnish <strong>in</strong>formation to<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>essmen and farmers about market prices, potential buyers <strong>in</strong> other locales and<br />

product quality. In exchange for this <strong>in</strong>formation, merchants paid the middlemen a fixed<br />

percentage of the profits. Two other types of middlemen <strong>in</strong> the early American market<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded the merchant middlemen and agent middlemen. Merchant middlemen, such as<br />

shipp<strong>in</strong>g merchants and importers, took title to the commodities that they handled. On<br />

34


the other hand, agent middlemen, such as factors, brokers, and auctioneers, acted for a<br />

pr<strong>in</strong>cipal and did not acquire title (Beniger, 1986; F. M. Jones, 1937).<br />

Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>in</strong> the Industrial Revolution<br />

The boom <strong>in</strong> technological advances and the expansion of national markets fueled<br />

the Industrial Revolution. Orig<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Great Brita<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> the years between 1750 and<br />

1830, and spread<strong>in</strong>g thereafter to the US and other European countries, the Industrial<br />

Revolution transformed national economies and completely restructured economic<br />

activities. Not only was there a major shift from agricultural production to manufactur<strong>in</strong>g;<br />

equally important, firms completely reorganized themselves <strong>in</strong> order to deal with grow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties associated with <strong>in</strong>dustrialization. Large-scale vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated firms soon<br />

replaced decentralized horizontal firms. As firms ga<strong>in</strong>ed control over their uncerta<strong>in</strong><br />

environments, the <strong>in</strong>termediary’s role radically changed.<br />

Technological <strong>in</strong>novations <strong>in</strong> transportation and communication revolutionized<br />

the way bus<strong>in</strong>ess was carried out. The new transport technologies developed dur<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

Industrial Revolution allowed producers, distributors and merchants to communicate<br />

much more easily and <strong>in</strong>crease the scope of their markets, thereby reduc<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties<br />

<strong>in</strong> distribution. Included were advances <strong>in</strong> coastal shipp<strong>in</strong>g, railways, and turnpikes, all of<br />

which eased transport <strong>in</strong> both Europe and the United States (Braudel, 1982a). Advances<br />

<strong>in</strong> transport technologies co<strong>in</strong>cided with advances <strong>in</strong> communication technologies. In the<br />

United States, the first federal postage stamp was <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> 1847, usher<strong>in</strong>g a national<br />

35


system of distribution and eas<strong>in</strong>g communication across great distances. In the mid-<br />

1800s, Samuel F. B. Morse <strong>in</strong>vented the telegraph system, mak<strong>in</strong>g it possible for firms to<br />

communicate <strong>in</strong>stantaneously at great distances. The commercialization of the telephone<br />

<strong>in</strong> the 1800’s was likewise critical to the development of a national communication<br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure (Beniger, 1986).<br />

As technologies advanced, the role of the <strong>in</strong>termediary evolved. The greater<br />

expansion of trade created new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong> distribution and sales as bus<strong>in</strong>esses sought<br />

new ways to control the markets at greater distances. Thus, the need for even greater<br />

coord<strong>in</strong>ation and control of <strong>in</strong>formation grew (Garcia, 2001, 11). Bus<strong>in</strong>esses that still<br />

relied on traditional middlemen to process market <strong>in</strong>formation were at a disadvantage.<br />

Middlemen that controlled the flow of <strong>in</strong>formation became bottlenecks, exert<strong>in</strong>g pressure<br />

upon bus<strong>in</strong>esses and narrow<strong>in</strong>g the marg<strong>in</strong> of profit—<strong>in</strong> effect, rais<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs<br />

(Garcia, 2001, 7) To avoid these added costs, and to reduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties, stronger<br />

producers sought to go around the middleman (Shaw, 1912, 728). For <strong>in</strong>stance, firms<br />

reduced their dependency on middlemen by vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrat<strong>in</strong>g the transportation of<br />

their goods <strong>in</strong>to their organizational hierarchy.<br />

Vertical <strong>in</strong>tegration began to take place at higher levels of the economic system,<br />

thus marg<strong>in</strong>aliz<strong>in</strong>g the role of the middleman further (Beniger, 1986, 159). With this<br />

reorganization, there was a decrease <strong>in</strong> the steps of production and thus a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the<br />

number of middlemen (Shaw, 1912, 728). These firms absorbed many of the functions<br />

36


normally divided between several <strong>in</strong>termediaries, such as transportation, distribution and<br />

sales. The functions once held by middlemen become <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>in</strong>to bus<strong>in</strong>esses that<br />

bought directly from manufacturers and sold to specialized retailers, elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g many<br />

functions of traditional middlemen (Beniger, 1986). 6<br />

Yet the Industrial Revolution did not br<strong>in</strong>g about a total ext<strong>in</strong>ction of middlemen.<br />

<strong>Intermediaries</strong> were still viable <strong>in</strong> cases where control was difficult and uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties were<br />

high. For new technologies <strong>in</strong>troduced new transaction costs <strong>in</strong>to the economy. As the<br />

distance between transactions grew, buyers and sellers had less knowledge about each<br />

other, so the possibility of opportunism and moral hazard <strong>in</strong>creased. Consumers and<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>esses also faced a problem of <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry. Moreover, as bus<strong>in</strong>esses<br />

sought to specialize, they had to deal with problems of greater asset specificity. New types<br />

of <strong>in</strong>termediaries appeared to reduce these transaction and agency costs. Whereas before,<br />

the <strong>in</strong>termediary was often a lone middleman, the Industrial Revolution saw the<br />

conception of firms act<strong>in</strong>g as <strong>in</strong>termediaries.<br />

One example of a new type of <strong>in</strong>termediary was the factor, or wholesaler<br />

middleman. Wholesalers and the wholesale market emerged <strong>in</strong> early 1800s to buffer<br />

6 Beniger give an example of this: “<strong>in</strong> textiles…jobbers supplied store that sold retail to consumers who, <strong>in</strong><br />

turn, either mad either made their own cloth<strong>in</strong>g or took the cloth to tailors. By the 1840s, however, the<br />

demand for ready-made cloth<strong>in</strong>g had been well enough established for manufacturer to <strong>in</strong>tegrate to a s<strong>in</strong>gle<br />

firm,” (Beniger, 1986, 159).<br />

37


sellers from the overproduction of goods associated with the use of new factory<br />

mach<strong>in</strong>ery (F. M. Jones, 1937, 10). Because it was difficult to establish a presence <strong>in</strong><br />

distant markets, merchants used several types of specialized wholesale <strong>in</strong>termediaries, such<br />

as commission agents, factors, and brokers, to work on their behalf. These middlemen<br />

resolved uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties concern<strong>in</strong>g the location of buyers and sellers, their credit stand<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

the market price, places and rate of storage, and transportation facilities (F. M. Jones,<br />

1937, 65-66). The wholesalers benefited consumers by expand<strong>in</strong>g the range of<br />

commodities on the market and reduc<strong>in</strong>g the search costs for f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g the goods.<br />

Another modification on the traditional <strong>in</strong>termediary was the auction. Auctions<br />

rose <strong>in</strong> popularity early <strong>in</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eteenth century, peak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the United States, between<br />

1825-1836 (Beniger, 1986, 147). Br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g buyers and sellers together <strong>in</strong> a central locale,<br />

the auction reduced uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty by facilitat<strong>in</strong>g the sort<strong>in</strong>g and distribution of imported<br />

goods with uncerta<strong>in</strong> values (Beniger, 1986). The efficiency of the auction underm<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

the role of traditional middlemen. In order to re-<strong>in</strong>sert themselves <strong>in</strong>to the value cha<strong>in</strong>,<br />

middlemen began to purchase directly from domestic and foreign manufactur<strong>in</strong>g agents<br />

for resale to local consumers. Because technology made communications between<br />

merchants and middlemen across long distances easier, many middlemen changed their<br />

role by becom<strong>in</strong>g importers (Beniger, 1986). By controll<strong>in</strong>g communication, this new type<br />

of <strong>in</strong>termediary was able to ga<strong>in</strong> predom<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational trade. Importers found a<br />

niche <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational markets where communication between distributors and<br />

38


manufacturers was deficient. They were thus able to reduce the ris<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs of<br />

do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess at great distances.<br />

Innovations <strong>in</strong> distribution and sales also reduced uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, thereby elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g<br />

certa<strong>in</strong> types of traditional middlemen. To control distribution costs, producers reduced<br />

the amount of <strong>in</strong>formation necessary to process <strong>in</strong>formation about commodities (Beniger,<br />

1986, 331). To this end, they developed standards <strong>in</strong> packag<strong>in</strong>g, sizes, weights, <strong>in</strong>spect<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

sort<strong>in</strong>g and prices (Beniger, 1986, 331). These <strong>in</strong>novations benefited consumers by<br />

reduc<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>in</strong> product quality and facilitat<strong>in</strong>g market transactions. Standards also<br />

reduced asymmetric <strong>in</strong>formation and adverse selection for consumers by act<strong>in</strong>g as a<br />

signal<strong>in</strong>g mechanism for quality. Consumers no longer needed middlemen to monitor the<br />

producer and control these uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties.<br />

In order to re-<strong>in</strong>sert themselves <strong>in</strong>to the value cha<strong>in</strong>, middlemen entered the field<br />

of standards and patents. They became specialized <strong>in</strong>termediaries—patent agents and<br />

lawyers—work<strong>in</strong>g on behalf of <strong>in</strong>ventors to distribute and license patents. These<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries stepped <strong>in</strong> dur<strong>in</strong>g a time of technological boom when uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties existed<br />

<strong>in</strong> the patent system, thereby reduc<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs by br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g buyers and sellers of<br />

patents together (Lamoreaux & Sokoloff, 2003).<br />

Along with these changes, the role of the <strong>in</strong>termediary as a distributor began to<br />

evolve. Technology advances allowed manufacturers to produce goods at an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly<br />

higher rate, so they needed to expand their sales outlets and <strong>in</strong>crease the speed of<br />

39


distribution (Beniger, 1986, 160). But once aga<strong>in</strong>, reduction <strong>in</strong> some uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties and<br />

their associated transaction costs gave rise to others. Even as bus<strong>in</strong>esses vertically<br />

<strong>in</strong>tegrated their distribution functions, they produced goods at faster and faster speeds;<br />

thus, to rega<strong>in</strong> control, they looked for middlemen to help speed up the distribution<br />

process. To meet this need, a new type of <strong>in</strong>termediary appeared on the scene: mass<br />

retailers, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g department stores, cha<strong>in</strong>s stores and mail-order services (Beniger, 1986,<br />

160). Mak<strong>in</strong>g note of this development <strong>in</strong> 1912, Shaw wrote: “the enormous growth of<br />

the mail order bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> recent years gives evidence that <strong>in</strong> some l<strong>in</strong>es of distribution<br />

there are economies <strong>in</strong> this system,” (730). Like wholesalers, these <strong>in</strong>termediary retail<br />

firms also served the consumer by expand<strong>in</strong>g the selection of goods offered, and eas<strong>in</strong>g<br />

acquisition of commodities.<br />

Technology advances altered the function of <strong>in</strong>termediaries by improv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

communication. Enhanced communication allowed producers to reach consumers more<br />

efficiently and effectively. Some firms vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated this function, but most sought<br />

the help of an <strong>in</strong>termediary. Thus, a new type of <strong>in</strong>termediary firm—media and<br />

advertis<strong>in</strong>g—developed. In particular, by us<strong>in</strong>g the po<strong>in</strong>t-to-multipo<strong>in</strong>t media such as<br />

catalogs, magaz<strong>in</strong>es and newspapers, producers could not only design their own messages,<br />

they could also reach a greater number of customers at much lower costs. It was more<br />

economical for a bus<strong>in</strong>ess to rely on an <strong>in</strong>termediary firm to distribute the message, rather<br />

than face high fixed costs to produce the media themselves. Thus, <strong>in</strong>termediaries<br />

40


specializ<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> mass media and advertis<strong>in</strong>g replaced traditional middlemen to convey<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation to consumers. This form of <strong>in</strong>termediary reduced <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry<br />

and search costs for consumers, while at the same time rais<strong>in</strong>g profits for bus<strong>in</strong>esses.<br />

Conclusion<br />

The Industrial Revolution transformed the function of <strong>in</strong>termediaries. Before the<br />

Industrial Revolution, <strong>in</strong>termediaries transported goods from producers to consumers,<br />

distributed goods, and provided communication l<strong>in</strong>ks. New technologies reduced these<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong> market transactions and thus elim<strong>in</strong>ated the functions of traditional<br />

middlemen. Yet, as the technological <strong>in</strong>novations <strong>in</strong>troduced new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties,<br />

middlemen stepped <strong>in</strong> to reduce them, re<strong>in</strong>vent<strong>in</strong>g themselves to reta<strong>in</strong> their value <strong>in</strong> the<br />

market.<br />

The cont<strong>in</strong>ual expansion from a town-centered market, to a commercial market<br />

and f<strong>in</strong>ally to an <strong>in</strong>ternational economy caused middlemen to evolve from simple store<br />

merchants <strong>in</strong>to <strong>in</strong>termediary firms. As the market widened, <strong>in</strong>dustries such as bank<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

stocks, <strong>in</strong>surance, advertis<strong>in</strong>g and market<strong>in</strong>g grew. Middlemen found new positions <strong>in</strong><br />

these service-oriented and <strong>in</strong>formation-rich <strong>in</strong>dustries. Thus, <strong>in</strong>termediary firms helped to<br />

control the flow and transfer of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly commodified <strong>in</strong>formation. In addition,<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries found new opportunities when unforeseen economic conditions gave rise<br />

41


to new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties (Shaw, 1912) 7 . In these roles, their functions changed from that of a<br />

s<strong>in</strong>gle distributor and communicator to an <strong>in</strong>formation broker and trusted source, work<strong>in</strong>g<br />

on behalf of the buyer and the seller to reduce transaction costs.<br />

For a seller to solicit an <strong>in</strong>termediary, the services needed to provide value. If an<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediary could not add value to the bus<strong>in</strong>ess, nor decrease transaction costs,<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>esses simply vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated the <strong>in</strong>termediary functions <strong>in</strong>to their own<br />

organizations. As new technologies decreased uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties for bus<strong>in</strong>esses, the challenge<br />

to the <strong>in</strong>termediary <strong>in</strong> the Industrial Revolution was to create new services for bus<strong>in</strong>esses<br />

that they could not do on their own. Most bus<strong>in</strong>esses found that <strong>in</strong>termediaries provided<br />

an efficient solution because they shared the risk <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> enter<strong>in</strong>g a new market, and<br />

they could absorb high sunk costs, especially those associated with advertis<strong>in</strong>g and retail<br />

sales.<br />

Technology helped bus<strong>in</strong>esses to expand their markets and <strong>in</strong>crease sales, but, at<br />

the same time, consumers faced greater uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties. The expansion of the market<br />

<strong>in</strong>troduced new goods and services <strong>in</strong>to the economy and left consumers with the difficult<br />

job of sort<strong>in</strong>g through their new options. Bus<strong>in</strong>esses grew <strong>in</strong> size and power, and<br />

7 “Suppose, for <strong>in</strong>stance, that the protective tariff system of the United States were to be swept away and<br />

free trade <strong>in</strong>stituted. The middleman could then draw upon the foreign producer for supplies of unbranded<br />

staple goods, which might serve to <strong>in</strong>crease his importance as a l<strong>in</strong>k <strong>in</strong> our system of distribution,” (Shaw,<br />

1912, 730)<br />

42


consumers faced ris<strong>in</strong>g problems of <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry and search costs. To ga<strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>formation about the market, which they could not gather on their own, consumers<br />

turned to <strong>in</strong>termediaries. Consumers found that the services offered by an <strong>in</strong>termediary<br />

helped to reduce their ris<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>ternational market.<br />

<strong>Intermediaries</strong> did best when they met both consumers’ and bus<strong>in</strong>esses’ needs.<br />

Thus, <strong>in</strong>termediaries that reduced transaction costs for both parties were most likely to<br />

succeed. Take, for example, the role of the <strong>in</strong>termediary as a mass retailer. Although<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>esses could have vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated this function and developed their own retail<br />

outlets, <strong>in</strong>stead they relied on the <strong>in</strong>termediary to do this for them. <strong>Intermediaries</strong> thrived<br />

<strong>in</strong> this role because they created value for both bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers. The prevalence<br />

of modern-day equivalents such as grocery stores and department stores proves that this is<br />

a viable role for <strong>in</strong>termediaries.<br />

Historical analysis of market transactions shows that, as markets became<br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly complex, the tendency to elim<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>in</strong>termediaries from transactions grew.<br />

Bus<strong>in</strong>esses vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated and marg<strong>in</strong>alized the role of the <strong>in</strong>termediary. As<br />

communications <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong> reach and scope, bus<strong>in</strong>esses accessed their customers more<br />

directly than ever before. When technology changed the bus<strong>in</strong>ess processes of the<br />

economy, <strong>in</strong>termediaries re<strong>in</strong>vented themselves to add value for both the buyer and the<br />

seller. Thus, there was a cont<strong>in</strong>ual cycle of <strong>in</strong>termediation—dis<strong>in</strong>termediation—re-<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediation as the economy changed (Chircu & Kauffman, 1998). The same is true for<br />

43


present day markets. What uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties have been resolved with new digital<br />

communications, and what new ones have arisen? How are new communications<br />

technologies chang<strong>in</strong>g the role of the <strong>in</strong>termediary <strong>in</strong> the digital age?<br />

44


Chapter 4. Technology and Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong> the Digital Age<br />

Introduction<br />

As we have seen dur<strong>in</strong>g the Industrial Revolution, the function of the <strong>in</strong>termediary<br />

evolved <strong>in</strong> relation to the advent of new technologies and the correspond<strong>in</strong>g rise and shift<br />

<strong>in</strong> the loci of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties. A similar phenomenon is occurr<strong>in</strong>g today. Build<strong>in</strong>g on the<br />

lessons of the previous chapter, we can now turn our attention to the present. To this<br />

end, this chapter def<strong>in</strong>es the emerg<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties that bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers face <strong>in</strong><br />

the digital age. In addition, it considers how present-day <strong>in</strong>termediaries must change their<br />

roles if they want to rema<strong>in</strong> viable economic actors <strong>in</strong> the new digital bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

environment.<br />

The chapter beg<strong>in</strong>s by briefly characteriz<strong>in</strong>g today’s technology advances,<br />

specifically computers, the Internet and e-commerce, and describ<strong>in</strong>g how they reduce<br />

some uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties while generat<strong>in</strong>g others. Next, and more specifically, the chapter looks<br />

at the grow<strong>in</strong>g collection of consumer <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> the digital economy and the<br />

associated uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties relat<strong>in</strong>g to issues of privacy and trust. F<strong>in</strong>ally, the chapter<br />

proposes the roles that <strong>in</strong>termediaries might play to help resolve these related<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties and risks.<br />

45


Digital technology advances<br />

Just as communication and transportation <strong>in</strong>novations drastically changed the<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustrial economy, so too advances <strong>in</strong> telecommunications and <strong>in</strong>formation technology<br />

are transform<strong>in</strong>g today’s economy. The term “digital revolution” characterizes these<br />

technological <strong>in</strong>novations. Digital technology and advances <strong>in</strong> process<strong>in</strong>g powers of<br />

computers <strong>in</strong>crease the scope, speed, reliability and efficiency of communications systems,<br />

chang<strong>in</strong>g the way <strong>in</strong> which economic actors process and transfer <strong>in</strong>formation. Computers<br />

translate data <strong>in</strong>to digitized bits and then send them via telephone wires, coaxial cables<br />

and fiber-optic cables to other computers across the globe. With sufficient speed and<br />

memory, computers can become an actual telecommunications medium. These systems<br />

process <strong>in</strong>formation at high speeds and capacity, greatly reduc<strong>in</strong>g communication<br />

expenses and transaction costs (Antonelli, 1992; Evans & Wurster, 2000; Gandy, 1993;<br />

National Research Council (U.S.) NII 2000 Steer<strong>in</strong>g Committee., 1996; Neuman,<br />

McKnight, & Solomon, 1997).<br />

Provid<strong>in</strong>g a platform for digital communication, the Internet and the World Wide<br />

Web constitute the most fundamental <strong>in</strong>novations of the era. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Jonscher, for<br />

example, the Internet ranks along with the pr<strong>in</strong>t<strong>in</strong>g press <strong>in</strong> terms of its wide-reach<strong>in</strong>g<br />

ramifications (1999, 159). Orig<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g dur<strong>in</strong>g the Cold War with<strong>in</strong> the defense community<br />

as a decentralized communication network that could withstand attack, the Internet (then<br />

the ARPANET) was further developed and promoted with<strong>in</strong> the academic community. It<br />

46


developed <strong>in</strong>to a global network, managed by NSFNET (National Science Foundation<br />

Network), provid<strong>in</strong>g a general data transfer service used for applications such as e-mail<br />

and file transfer (Blumenthal & Clark, 2001; Harris & Hansen, n.d.; Jonscher, 1999).<br />

The Internet, a virtual network, connects users across the world. “The Internet<br />

has undone what Columbus discovered 500 years ago: it has made the earth flat once<br />

aga<strong>in</strong>,” (National Research Council (U.S.) NII 2000 Steer<strong>in</strong>g Committee., 1996, 149). It is<br />

a decentralized “network of networks” def<strong>in</strong>ed by <strong>in</strong>terface protocols, which do not rely<br />

on corporate structure, physical routes or boundaries. The <strong>in</strong>terconnectivity, flexibility,<br />

extensibility, and <strong>in</strong>ternetwork<strong>in</strong>g of the Internet enable it to change as new technologies<br />

and service requirements emerge (National Research Council (U.S.) NII 2000 Steer<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Committee., 1996; Neuman et al., 1997; Sr<strong>in</strong>agesh & Gong, 1996).<br />

In the 1990’s, after the development of the World Wide Web, the Internet<br />

diffused beyond universities and the government. Anticipat<strong>in</strong>g greater participation from<br />

the private sector, the government replaced the NSFNET <strong>in</strong>frastructure with commercial<br />

networks. This commercialization promoted further development of browser applications<br />

for the World Wide Web. Supported by HTML standards for encod<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation, the<br />

World Wide Web is a user-<strong>in</strong>terface application that allows content providers to format<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation for use on the Internet (Bailey & Bakos, 1997; Harris & Hansen, n.d.;<br />

Jonscher, 1999; National Research Council (U.S.) NII 2000 Steer<strong>in</strong>g Committee., 1996).<br />

47


With the government’s new privatization and commercialization policy, e-<br />

commerce exploded. The use of electronic networks for bus<strong>in</strong>ess transactions actually<br />

began <strong>in</strong> the 1970’s <strong>in</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>ancial sector, when money was first transferred between<br />

economic <strong>in</strong>stitutions via telecommunications networks (Barnes & Hunt, 2001). The<br />

World Wide Web provided a new platform for electronic commerce by <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g a new<br />

way to communicate and distribute and trade goods and services. Tak<strong>in</strong>g advantage of<br />

technology advances, <strong>in</strong>novative entrepreneurs set out to create a new market (Bailey &<br />

Bakos, 1997). They developed mechanisms to carry out virtual transactions between<br />

buyers and sellers that entailed the sale of products, services and <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong><br />

cyberspace (Turban et al., 2000, as cited by Barnes & Hunt, 2001, 1).<br />

One advantage of e-commerce is that it can expedite transactions and reduce<br />

transaction costs. In fact, as Shapiro and Varian note, e-commerce allows for a “friction-<br />

free” market, where search costs are m<strong>in</strong>imized (1998, 127). The Internet facilitates e-<br />

commerce by allow<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>esses to reach consumers directly. At the same time, the<br />

Internet provides consumers with expanded choices and search capabilities. Us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

automated search eng<strong>in</strong>es that seek out and sort <strong>in</strong>formation, consumers can do their own<br />

search<strong>in</strong>g on the World Wide Web. Thus, the Internet serves both bus<strong>in</strong>esses’ and<br />

consumers’ needs, reduc<strong>in</strong>g the cost, time, and effort required to acquire market<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation. These benefits are, moreover, synergistic, giv<strong>in</strong>g rise to network externalities<br />

48


and <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g returns. The more consumers and bus<strong>in</strong>esses participate <strong>in</strong> the system, the<br />

greater the benefits for all (Bakos, 1991; Karake-Shalhoub, 2002; McMillan, 2002).<br />

Insofar as the benefits of e-commerce are related <strong>in</strong>formation costs, they affect the<br />

role of the <strong>in</strong>termediary. Thus, early on, observers predicted that dis<strong>in</strong>termediation would<br />

take place, given the ability of bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers to reach each other directly via<br />

the World Wide Web (Chircu & Kauffman, 2001, 50). Observers anticipated that<br />

dis<strong>in</strong>termediation would be greatest <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>tense <strong>in</strong>dustries such as f<strong>in</strong>ance,<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance, travel and book sellers (Downes & Mui, 1998; Scott, 2000, 5). The chang<strong>in</strong>g<br />

role of travel agencies provides a good example. On the World Wide Web, customers can<br />

f<strong>in</strong>d the best deal and make travel arrangements themselves (Stand<strong>in</strong>g & Vasudavan,<br />

2001). Likewise, <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial markets, <strong>in</strong>vestors can bypass traditional brokers and f<strong>in</strong>d<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>formation on the Web (Downes & Mui, 1998).<br />

New uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties<br />

As seen <strong>in</strong> chapter three, although technologies reduce some uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties and<br />

transaction costs, they simultaneously engender others. Thus, it should not be surpris<strong>in</strong>g<br />

that, contrary to <strong>in</strong>itial predictions, e-commerce is not a “friction free” market. Certa<strong>in</strong>ly,<br />

the shift to a cyber marketplace has affected the organization of economic relationships,<br />

markets and firms (Evans & Wurster, 2000). However, uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties and transaction costs<br />

cont<strong>in</strong>ue to confound bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers alike. The myriad sources of these<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties are discussed briefly below.<br />

49


i. <strong>Information</strong> overload<br />

E-commerce <strong>in</strong>creases the amount of <strong>in</strong>formation exchanged between buyers and<br />

sellers, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation overload. Even when customers use an automated search<br />

eng<strong>in</strong>e to seek out sellers, they still are confronted by vast amounts of <strong>in</strong>formation. Given<br />

all the options available to them, consumers f<strong>in</strong>d it hard to differentiate between<br />

trustworthy or opportunistic bus<strong>in</strong>esses. As a result of these transaction costs, they are<br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly bounded <strong>in</strong> their ability to make ‘rational’ choices (Ba, Wh<strong>in</strong>ston, & Zhang,<br />

2000, 190).<br />

ii. <strong>Information</strong> asymmetry<br />

The <strong>in</strong>ability of consumers to process all the <strong>in</strong>formation available to them <strong>in</strong> an e-<br />

commerce environment exacerbates <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry. Onl<strong>in</strong>e, it is much harder to<br />

ensure product quality, or verify the reputation of a bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Hence, <strong>in</strong> a virtual<br />

environment, bus<strong>in</strong>esses have an advantage to the extent that they have more and better<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation than buyers. For example, on e-commerce websites, <strong>in</strong>formation can be<br />

counterfeited, forged or misrepresented. As a result, a ‘lemon market’ ensues, lead<strong>in</strong>g to<br />

<strong>in</strong>efficient transactions and market failures. Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties, transaction costs and agency<br />

costs for both buyers and sellers <strong>in</strong>crease (Ba et al., 2000).<br />

50


iii. Technology<br />

Technology itself creates new forms of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty. For example, consumers may<br />

be weary of technical malfunctions, failures or hackers. Consumers may be unwill<strong>in</strong>g to<br />

provide their credit card <strong>in</strong>formation onl<strong>in</strong>e or personal <strong>in</strong>formation, fearful that it will<br />

end up <strong>in</strong> the wrong hands, or that the bus<strong>in</strong>ess will overcharge them or misuse their<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation. They may also hesitate to order goods or services onl<strong>in</strong>e because they are<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong> that the transaction will go through. This unfamiliarity of technology causes<br />

greater moral hazard and risk for consumers. If there is a problem, bus<strong>in</strong>esses can escape<br />

responsibility by blam<strong>in</strong>g technical glitches (Karake-Shalhoub, 2002).<br />

iv. Onl<strong>in</strong>e strategy<br />

New uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties also arise from the need of bus<strong>in</strong>esses to redef<strong>in</strong>e themselves<br />

for e-commerce. E-commerce is so new that traditional bus<strong>in</strong>esses have a hard time<br />

f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g the best strategy to capitalize on it. Caught by the legacy of their own success,<br />

established firms hesitate to tread <strong>in</strong>to the uncerta<strong>in</strong> territory of e-commerce. Many<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>esses cont<strong>in</strong>ue to employ current bus<strong>in</strong>ess models, treat<strong>in</strong>g their website as a static<br />

entity, such as a catalogue or a publish<strong>in</strong>g medium. They do not capitalize on the<br />

opportunities provided by the enhanced communication channels to their consumers. By<br />

not tak<strong>in</strong>g full advantage of the dynamic capabilities that the Web has to offer, bus<strong>in</strong>esses<br />

51


isk stagnation and competitive disadvantage as new, web-only entrants surpass them<br />

(Karake-Shalhoub, 2002).<br />

v. Mass customization<br />

Given the global scope of e-commerce, bus<strong>in</strong>esses now face <strong>in</strong>tense competition,<br />

a major source of new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties. In a global environment, bus<strong>in</strong>esses must be more<br />

responsive and adaptive to consumers than ever before. For example, new manufactur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

technologies, the <strong>in</strong>creased speed of technological change and a shortened product life<br />

cycle, as well as the shift<strong>in</strong>g nature of customer demand, necessitate that bus<strong>in</strong>esses<br />

change their strategies. Firms can no longer compete by offer<strong>in</strong>g standardized products;<br />

rather, they must meet consumer demand for greater product variety and higher quality<br />

products and services. To this end, firms are adopt<strong>in</strong>g mass customization strategies,<br />

which allow them to personalize products and provide greater variety while still benefit<strong>in</strong>g<br />

from economies of scale and scope. To these ends, bus<strong>in</strong>esses rely on ‘just-<strong>in</strong>-time’<br />

manufactur<strong>in</strong>g, quality control, and ‘customer-fac<strong>in</strong>g’ bus<strong>in</strong>ess plans that strengthen<br />

exist<strong>in</strong>g customer relations. More and more, bus<strong>in</strong>esses take notice of their customers,<br />

listen<strong>in</strong>g to them and apply<strong>in</strong>g their feedback (Dutta & Segev, 2001; Kotha, 1995; Wolters<br />

& Hoogeweegen, 2001).<br />

52


vi. Asset specificity and networked firms<br />

As firms beg<strong>in</strong> specializ<strong>in</strong>g and customiz<strong>in</strong>g, they face asset specificity, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong><br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and ris<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs. These specialized firms experience lock-<strong>in</strong> once<br />

they have made a significant <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> a specific asset. One strategy that bus<strong>in</strong>esses<br />

are adopt<strong>in</strong>g to address these new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties is vertical dis<strong>in</strong>tegration. Although<br />

vertical <strong>in</strong>tegration served well to reduce transaction costs <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustrial era, it is<br />

unsuitable for the digital age. Instead, firms specialize <strong>in</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong> part of the value cha<strong>in</strong><br />

and build alliances and partners, thus outsourc<strong>in</strong>g unessential activities. Networked firms<br />

enter <strong>in</strong>to contracts and hold jo<strong>in</strong>t assets to share the risks of operat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a rapidly<br />

chang<strong>in</strong>g technological landscape (Downes & Mui, 1998; Sarkar, Butler, & Ste<strong>in</strong>field,<br />

1995; C. Shapiro & Varian, 1998).<br />

vii. <strong>Information</strong> commodities<br />

Many networked firms profit not from tangible goods, but <strong>in</strong>tangible <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

assets, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>creased uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty. For example, by exploit<strong>in</strong>g the unique features<br />

of the Internet, <strong>in</strong>formation producers can trade <strong>in</strong>formation for a price <strong>in</strong> the market<br />

(Gandy, 1993; C. Shapiro & Varian, 1998). To maximize their profits, these producers<br />

control access and distribution of <strong>in</strong>formation by enforc<strong>in</strong>g patents and copyrights,<br />

mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation scarce. <strong>Information</strong> asymmetry <strong>in</strong>creases as a result. Yet, at the same<br />

time, producers are also experienc<strong>in</strong>g greater uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties. For ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>tellectual<br />

53


property rights is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly problematic, given digital technologies that allow <strong>in</strong>dividuals<br />

to access, reproduce, and retransmit <strong>in</strong>formation without permission of the producer.<br />

Thus, as <strong>in</strong>tangible goods become <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly profitable, their value is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly<br />

difficult to protect. As the Electronic Frontier Foundation’s John Perry Barlow said,<br />

“<strong>in</strong>formation wants to be free,” (Downes & Mui, 1998, 49-50). Perhaps he should have<br />

said, “consumers want <strong>in</strong>formation to be free.” For <strong>in</strong>formation producers to make a<br />

profit, <strong>in</strong>formation must reta<strong>in</strong> economic value as a commodity. Without a f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

<strong>in</strong>centive for producers to create <strong>in</strong>formation, the production of <strong>in</strong>formation will slacken.<br />

Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty arises from the conflict<strong>in</strong>g demands to commodify <strong>in</strong>formation and to<br />

distribute it for free over the Internet (Evans & Wurster, 2000; Loebbecke, 2001).<br />

viii. Personal <strong>in</strong>formation collection<br />

To ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> control and develop <strong>in</strong>formation-based strategies, bus<strong>in</strong>esses must<br />

f<strong>in</strong>d new ways to create value from their <strong>in</strong>tangible assets through customer relations,<br />

reputation and consumer <strong>in</strong>formation. In fact, to employ a mass customization strategy,<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>esses must ga<strong>in</strong> a deeper understand<strong>in</strong>g of their customers. Today’s technologies<br />

allow bus<strong>in</strong>esses to do so. Thus, when consumers search the Internet, browser<br />

applications place ‘cookies” <strong>in</strong>side their computer to track their activities, record<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

websites they visit and the <strong>in</strong>formation they provide. Profiled <strong>in</strong> huge databases, this<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation is used to target advertisements and messages to customers based on their<br />

demographics and behavioral profiles that factor <strong>in</strong> race, gender, age, class, education,<br />

54


health, sexuality, and consumptive behavior (J. E. Campbell & Carlson, 2002). This<br />

personal <strong>in</strong>formation is itself commodified, and bought and sold, often without the<br />

knowledge of or permission from the consumer (J. E. Campbell & Carlson, 2002; Evans<br />

& Wurster, 2000). In this sense, consumers are themselves commodified.<br />

Consumers, likewise, play a role <strong>in</strong> this process. Conv<strong>in</strong>ced that the ga<strong>in</strong>s from e-<br />

commerce are greater than the privacy costs that they <strong>in</strong>cur, many consumers will<strong>in</strong>gly<br />

provide their personal <strong>in</strong>formation. Others may be unaware of this asymmetrical<br />

exchange because the surveillance is often not made explicit. As Campbell and Carlson<br />

have po<strong>in</strong>ted out, consumers engage <strong>in</strong> self-disclosure, even though the terms are rarely<br />

negotiable, because they do not want to be excluded from participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the<br />

marketplace 8 (J. E. Campbell & Carlson, 2002).<br />

ix. Privacy<br />

Given bus<strong>in</strong>esses’ greater access to personal <strong>in</strong>formation, consumers face greater<br />

moral hazard and risk. Thus, privacy concerns are becom<strong>in</strong>g a major source of<br />

8 Campbell and Carlson refer to this phenomenon as a “Consumerist Panopticon,” allud<strong>in</strong>g to Michel<br />

Foucault’s conceptualization of the Panopticon as a function of surveillance <strong>in</strong> modern <strong>in</strong>stitutions, notably<br />

prisons, workplaces, cl<strong>in</strong>ics, educational <strong>in</strong>stitutions and governments. Their model implies that if you do<br />

not engage <strong>in</strong> self-disclosure of <strong>in</strong>formation, you will be punished by be<strong>in</strong>g excluded from the rewards of the<br />

marketplace. Transactions are <strong>in</strong>equitable as producers or suppliers set the terms of a contract, which a<br />

consumer can only accept or decl<strong>in</strong>e (2002).<br />

55


uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty for today’s consumers, and the consumers bear the additional transaction and<br />

agency costs. Consumers have no <strong>in</strong>formation privacy, and are uncerta<strong>in</strong> of how their<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation will be handled by bus<strong>in</strong>esses, so they are less likely to engage <strong>in</strong> e-commerce<br />

transactions (Cavoukian, 2002, 40-41) 9 . A series of surveys conducted by Harris and<br />

Associates show that consumers are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly concerned about their privacy onl<strong>in</strong>e.<br />

They feel that bus<strong>in</strong>esses collect too much personal <strong>in</strong>formation, over which consumers<br />

have little control. At the same time, however, consumers do not equate customer<br />

profiles with a loss of privacy, and thus they are will<strong>in</strong>g to provide personal <strong>in</strong>formation to<br />

companies <strong>in</strong> exchange for specialized services and products (Leickly, 2003). 10<br />

9 <strong>Information</strong> privacy is the ability of an <strong>in</strong>dividual to control the access, use and disclosure of one’s<br />

personal <strong>in</strong>formation(Cavoukian, 2002)<br />

10 An analysis of two Harris and Associates surveys, orig<strong>in</strong>ally collected <strong>in</strong> 1990 and 1998.<br />

For my purposes, I focused on six questions:<br />

(1) How concerned are you about threat to your personal privacy <strong>in</strong> America today?<br />

(2) How confident are you that bus<strong>in</strong>esses use personal and confidential <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> a proper manner?<br />

(3) How strongly do you agree or disagree with the follow<strong>in</strong>g statement? Consumers have lost all control<br />

over how personal <strong>in</strong>formation is circulated and used by companies.<br />

(4) How strongly do you agree or disagree with the follow<strong>in</strong>g statement? Bus<strong>in</strong>ess organizations generally<br />

ask for too much personal <strong>in</strong>formation from consumers.<br />

(5) How acceptable would it be for bus<strong>in</strong>esses you deal with to use <strong>in</strong>formation from your customer profile<br />

to <strong>in</strong>form you of exist<strong>in</strong>g and new products and services that these bus<strong>in</strong>esses provide, and that they th<strong>in</strong>k<br />

would be of <strong>in</strong>terest to you?<br />

56


Nonetheless, without greater privacy guarantees, consumers may be less will<strong>in</strong>g to<br />

engage <strong>in</strong> e-commerce. It is important to note <strong>in</strong> this regard that consumers are less likely<br />

to perceive <strong>in</strong>formation practices as privacy <strong>in</strong>fr<strong>in</strong>gement under the follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

circumstances:<br />

1. <strong>Information</strong> is collected <strong>in</strong> the context of an exist<strong>in</strong>g relationship;<br />

2. They perceive that they have the ability to control future use of the <strong>in</strong>formation;<br />

(6) Dur<strong>in</strong>g the past year, have you or has a member of your household purchased goods or services through<br />

the Internet, or not?<br />

Results show that concerns for privacy were greater <strong>in</strong> 1998 than <strong>in</strong> 1990, before the commercialization of<br />

the Internet and the World Wide Web (significant at the .0005 level). The analysis concluded that as the<br />

feel<strong>in</strong>g of a loss of control over personal <strong>in</strong>formation and a feel<strong>in</strong>g that bus<strong>in</strong>esses ask for too much<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>creases, the concern for threats to privacy <strong>in</strong>crease as well. Individuals who had purchased<br />

goods on the Internet over the past year were not more or less likely to feel an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g concern to<br />

privacy.<br />

These f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs confirm that consumers have a greater concern for personal privacy <strong>in</strong> the digital age. They<br />

feel that bus<strong>in</strong>esses are collect<strong>in</strong>g too much personal <strong>in</strong>formation, that there is a loss of control of personal<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation, and there is less confidence <strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>esses’ use of personal <strong>in</strong>formation. Interest<strong>in</strong>gly, the<br />

results showed that most consumers did not equate customer profiles with a loss of privacy. Consumers are<br />

will<strong>in</strong>g to provide personal <strong>in</strong>formation to companies if, <strong>in</strong> return, the companies provide specialized<br />

services and products. Nonetheless, these f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs suggest that bus<strong>in</strong>esses will need to reth<strong>in</strong>k their use and<br />

57


3. The <strong>in</strong>formation collected or used is relevant to the transaction; and<br />

4. They believe the <strong>in</strong>formation will be used to draw reliable and valid <strong>in</strong>ferences<br />

about them. (Culnan, 1993, 345)<br />

x. Trust<br />

Not surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, given high transaction costs, e-commerce requires a high level of<br />

trust. 11 For trust to exist, consumers must believe that bus<strong>in</strong>esses will deliver goods and<br />

services of high quality and <strong>in</strong> the manner promised. Ironically, as communication costs<br />

decrease, the costs of build<strong>in</strong>g trust and reputation <strong>in</strong>crease (Karake-Shalhoub, 2002, 29).<br />

Trust is developed over time, and through repeated <strong>in</strong>teractions. However, <strong>in</strong> onl<strong>in</strong>e<br />

markets, such relationships are hard to establish and foster. Paradoxically, a new bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

can only succeed if it builds strong relationships with customers; yet, customers are less<br />

likely to trust and <strong>in</strong>teract with an unknown bus<strong>in</strong>ess.<br />

To protect aga<strong>in</strong>st uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and generate trust <strong>in</strong> onl<strong>in</strong>e transactions, bus<strong>in</strong>esses<br />

can employ conventional agency methods. For example, standards and contracts generate<br />

application of consumer <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> the 21st century, so that both the bus<strong>in</strong>ess and the consumer benefit<br />

(Leickly, 2003).<br />

11 “Trust is the essential lubricant of Web bus<strong>in</strong>ess; without trust, bus<strong>in</strong>ess gr<strong>in</strong>ds to a halt,” (Karake-<br />

Shalhoub, 2002, 157).<br />

58


trust and protect aga<strong>in</strong>st opportunism and moral hazard (Palmer, Bailey, & Faraj, 2000, 5-<br />

6). Also, to foster repeat transactions, bus<strong>in</strong>esses can build a positive reputation through<br />

brand<strong>in</strong>g. If these methods fail, a trusted third party can <strong>in</strong>tervene, vouch<strong>in</strong>g for the<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Third parties can capitalize on their own reputation to encourage repeat service<br />

and trust for their clients, preserv<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>tegrity of e-commerce markets (Karake-<br />

Shalhoub, 2002; Palmer et al., 2000; Scott, 2000, 8).<br />

New roles for <strong>in</strong>termediaries<br />

New types of specialized <strong>in</strong>termediaries are emerg<strong>in</strong>g to contend with the new<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties of the digital age. Digital <strong>in</strong>termediaries support the <strong>in</strong>teraction of buyers<br />

and sellers, stepp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> to facilitate the organization of e-commerce (Sarkar et al., 1995).<br />

These <strong>in</strong>termediaries help consumers deal with <strong>in</strong>formation overload and <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

asymmetry by sort<strong>in</strong>g, rout<strong>in</strong>g and filter<strong>in</strong>g, compar<strong>in</strong>g prices and vouch<strong>in</strong>g for worth<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

of products and firms (Kelly, 1998, 101). For example, search eng<strong>in</strong>es on the Internet<br />

turn up thousands of results, caus<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>dividual to <strong>in</strong>vest time <strong>in</strong> sort<strong>in</strong>g through and<br />

filter<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>formation. An <strong>in</strong>termediary adds value to the consumer by sort<strong>in</strong>g through<br />

the <strong>in</strong>formation, help<strong>in</strong>g to f<strong>in</strong>d the best match (M. D. Smith et al., 2000, 122).<br />

<strong>Intermediaries</strong> reduce the uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties that arise from recently restructured<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess organizations <strong>in</strong> a networked economy. When a networked firm vertically<br />

dis<strong>in</strong>tegrates and out-sources its non-essential services, new <strong>in</strong>termediaries appear on the<br />

scene. The nodes that connect firms <strong>in</strong> a networked economy are <strong>in</strong>termediaries, and the<br />

59


more connections a firm has, the more roles there are for an <strong>in</strong>termediary (Kelly, 1998).<br />

To add value for bus<strong>in</strong>esses, <strong>in</strong>termediaries reduce the transaction costs <strong>in</strong> nearly every<br />

activity for functions outside of the firm. They f<strong>in</strong>d niches <strong>in</strong> vertically dis<strong>in</strong>tegrated<br />

markets, offer specialized services and assume a portion of the risks <strong>in</strong>volved (Chircu &<br />

Kauffman, 2001; Downes & Mui, 1998; Sarkar et al., 1995).<br />

The uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong> specialized digital <strong>in</strong>formation markets signal a new<br />

opportunity for <strong>in</strong>termediaries as well. <strong>Intermediaries</strong> help <strong>in</strong>formation producers<br />

ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> control of their <strong>in</strong>tangible assets by facilitat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation transactions, giv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

producers <strong>in</strong>centive to create new <strong>in</strong>formation goods. Because distribution of <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

on digital networks costs nearly noth<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong>termediaries can step <strong>in</strong> to bundle and<br />

distribute large amounts of <strong>in</strong>formation goods <strong>in</strong> a more efficient manner than if each<br />

piece of <strong>in</strong>formation were sold or distributed separately, act<strong>in</strong>g as an <strong>in</strong>formation broker<br />

or ‘<strong>in</strong>fomediary’ (Bailey & Bakos, 1997, 9). As Grover and Teng so aptly put it:<br />

“<strong>in</strong>fomediaries are to <strong>in</strong>formation markets <strong>in</strong> the electronic marketspace what<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries, such as wholesalers and retailers, are to physical markets <strong>in</strong> more<br />

traditional marketspaces,” (Grover & Teng, 2001, 79). To ga<strong>in</strong> competitive advantage,<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediaries become experts <strong>in</strong> one particular area or a limited number of areas,<br />

benefit<strong>in</strong>g consumers with expert advise (Evans & Wurster, 2000, 96). Furthermore,<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediaries can serve consumers by help<strong>in</strong>g them to protect, manage and control the<br />

use of their personal <strong>in</strong>formation, thus alleviat<strong>in</strong>g privacy concerns.<br />

60


Network effects determ<strong>in</strong>e the success or failure of an <strong>in</strong>fomediary. Infomediaries<br />

require large <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> system development and ma<strong>in</strong>tenance costs, but they reap<br />

economies of scale by dissem<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation to a large population, and the<br />

<strong>in</strong>cremental costs for add<strong>in</strong>g users is low. Thus, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries must obta<strong>in</strong> a first-mover<br />

advantage, and create a critical mass to susta<strong>in</strong> a competitive edge. When critical mass is<br />

achieved, the high sunk costs necessary for creat<strong>in</strong>g the service are leveraged over all the<br />

users. The ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive for <strong>in</strong>fomediaries is profit, determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the value the services<br />

can create for potential clients—both bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers (Bakos, 1991; Loebbecke,<br />

2001; Rose, 1999; C. Shapiro & Varian, 1998).<br />

i. Rules for success<br />

Like <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> historical markets, <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> the digital age must<br />

provide value for both consumers and bus<strong>in</strong>esses. For consumers, the Internet provides<br />

complete and objective <strong>in</strong>formation about products. Consumers’ access to complete<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation is at odds with bus<strong>in</strong>esses’ <strong>in</strong>terests, because ideally, the best market would be<br />

one that provides biased <strong>in</strong>formation about their products to <strong>in</strong>fluence the consumer.<br />

Thus, an <strong>in</strong>termediary must determ<strong>in</strong>e the balance between the consumer’s needs for<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation and a producer’s needs for <strong>in</strong>fluence, while at the same time creat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

economic value for itself. Any <strong>in</strong>termediary that does not successfully balance these needs<br />

will ultimately fail (Bailey & Bakos, 1997; Sarkar et al., 1995, 11).<br />

61


The success of digital <strong>in</strong>termediaries also depends on whether or not they can<br />

promote trust <strong>in</strong> e-commerce. Many customers hesitate to make purchases onl<strong>in</strong>e because<br />

the <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> the transaction are unfamiliar and hence untrustworthy,<br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the perceived level of risk. A study performed <strong>in</strong> 2002 by the Georgia Institute<br />

of Technology found that all <strong>in</strong>termediaries—banks, credit card companies, e-commerce<br />

portals, and third parties—are not perceived as equally trustworthy. Incumbents such as<br />

eBay and Amazon.com tend to be more trusted than lesser-known onl<strong>in</strong>e retailers<br />

(Ghosen, 2002). Moreover, consumers are more likely to trust <strong>in</strong>termediaries that<br />

represent many producers, because this implies that they will be less biased (Sarkar et al.,<br />

1995, 15). For example, trusted <strong>in</strong>termediaries sort through different news media outlets<br />

to f<strong>in</strong>d correct <strong>in</strong>formation and news. For this type of <strong>in</strong>termediary to be successful, the<br />

consumer must be assured that they are receiv<strong>in</strong>g unbiased news accounts (A. L. Shapiro,<br />

1999, 190).<br />

Digital-age <strong>in</strong>termediaries: The seven rules for success<br />

1. Provide value for bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers.<br />

2. Promote trust <strong>in</strong> onl<strong>in</strong>e transactions.<br />

3. Become experts <strong>in</strong> specialized <strong>in</strong>dustries.<br />

4. Respect <strong>in</strong>formation privacy.<br />

5. Achieve critical mass.<br />

6. Ga<strong>in</strong> first-mover advantage.<br />

7. Take advantage of <strong>in</strong>formation commodities.<br />

62


Conclusion<br />

Contrary to enthusiasts’ claims, the Internet is not a “friction free” market. The<br />

reduction of transaction costs <strong>in</strong> the digital age does not elim<strong>in</strong>ate all uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties.<br />

Rather, as search costs and communication costs decrease, new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties arise.<br />

Bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers face new transaction costs, particularly <strong>in</strong> establish<strong>in</strong>g trust <strong>in</strong><br />

e-commerce. Technology allows bus<strong>in</strong>esses to offer consumers <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly customized<br />

and personalized services, but there is a trade-off, as consumers must contend with<br />

grow<strong>in</strong>g privacy concerns. Furthermore, competition is fierce <strong>in</strong> the global networked<br />

economy, and bus<strong>in</strong>esses that do not change their strategies face collapse.<br />

Predictions of a “frictionless” market threatened to make traditional <strong>in</strong>termediaries<br />

irrelevant. But similar to <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> the Industrial Revolution, <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> the<br />

digital age f<strong>in</strong>d value <strong>in</strong> other functions by exploit<strong>in</strong>g the new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties. Once aga<strong>in</strong>, it<br />

is a case of the <strong>in</strong>termediation-dis<strong>in</strong>termediation-re<strong>in</strong>termediation cycle (Chircu &<br />

Kauffman, 1998).<br />

<strong>Intermediaries</strong> have viable roles to play <strong>in</strong> the digital age. They succeed <strong>in</strong><br />

specialized markets by offer<strong>in</strong>g expertise on products and services. They reduce<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation overload by simplify<strong>in</strong>g search processes for consumers. Most importantly,<br />

they help to establish trust <strong>in</strong> e-commerce markets. Trust is a vital part of onl<strong>in</strong>e<br />

transact<strong>in</strong>g for bus<strong>in</strong>esses, consumers and <strong>in</strong>termediaries. With any abuse of trust, a firm<br />

or <strong>in</strong>termediary is likely to fail.<br />

63


Another possible role for <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> the digital age is the “<strong>in</strong>fomediary”: an<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediary specializ<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the broker<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>in</strong>formation for consumers and bus<strong>in</strong>esses.<br />

These <strong>in</strong>fomediaries have the potential to facilitate onl<strong>in</strong>e transactions, reduce <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

asymmetry and <strong>in</strong>formation overload, and protect privacy <strong>in</strong> onl<strong>in</strong>e transactions. The next<br />

chapter exam<strong>in</strong>es a sem<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>fomediary bus<strong>in</strong>ess model, several <strong>in</strong>fomediary firms that<br />

followed this model, and other onl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>termediary firms. As our historical analysis<br />

shows, wholesalers ga<strong>in</strong>ed importance dur<strong>in</strong>g the early years of the Industrial Revolution,<br />

and then faced dis<strong>in</strong>termediation as the market became more efficient. They were forced<br />

to re<strong>in</strong>vent themselves and re<strong>in</strong>sert themselves <strong>in</strong>to the value cha<strong>in</strong>. If <strong>in</strong>fomediaries are<br />

the wholesalers of the digital age, do they face the same fate? Will <strong>in</strong>fomediaries succeed<br />

<strong>in</strong> the digital age? If not, what types of <strong>in</strong>termediaries will?<br />

64


Introduction<br />

Chapter 5. Infomediaries <strong>in</strong> e-Commerce: Case Studies<br />

New uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong> the digital age are transform<strong>in</strong>g the role of the <strong>in</strong>termediary.<br />

Bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers now face problems of <strong>in</strong>formation overload, privacy concerns<br />

and lack of trust <strong>in</strong> onl<strong>in</strong>e transactions. Like <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> the Industrial Revolution,<br />

digital <strong>in</strong>termediaries must address these new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties and re<strong>in</strong>vent their roles to<br />

rema<strong>in</strong> viable. In particular, a new type of <strong>in</strong>termediary—an “<strong>in</strong>fomediary”—has<br />

emerged. Because almost all onl<strong>in</strong>e activities require search<strong>in</strong>g for, obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, and<br />

process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> some form or another, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries step <strong>in</strong> to simplify the<br />

process, becom<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation brokers.<br />

In 1999, John Hagel and Marc S<strong>in</strong>ger laid out a bus<strong>in</strong>ess plan for a specific k<strong>in</strong>d of<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary <strong>in</strong> their book Net Worth. Shortly after the book’s release, several companies<br />

set out to launch <strong>in</strong>fomediary services. This chapter exam<strong>in</strong>es these hopefuls, and seeks<br />

to determ<strong>in</strong>e why Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s <strong>in</strong>fomediary model failed to make an impact <strong>in</strong> e-<br />

commerce. In addition, it seeks to determ<strong>in</strong>e why other digital-age <strong>in</strong>termediaries have<br />

had greater success.<br />

To this end, this chapter first describes Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s <strong>in</strong>fomediary model, and<br />

considers its potential to alleviate transaction costs and uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties. Second, it exam<strong>in</strong>es<br />

three bus<strong>in</strong>esses efforts—Lumeria, AllAdvantage and Passport—based on Hagel and<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ger’s plan and analyzes why <strong>in</strong>fomediaries failed. Third, it considers two successful<br />

65


onl<strong>in</strong>e merchants—eBay and Amazon.com—to determ<strong>in</strong>e how they act as <strong>in</strong>termediaries<br />

to generate trust and facilitate transactions.<br />

Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s <strong>in</strong>fomediary model<br />

John Hagel and Marc S<strong>in</strong>ger propose an <strong>in</strong>fomediary bus<strong>in</strong>ess model <strong>in</strong> the book<br />

Net Worth: Shap<strong>in</strong>g Markets When Customers Make the Rules (1999). They recommend that<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediaries act as a trusted third party to aggregate customer <strong>in</strong>formation, us<strong>in</strong>g their<br />

comb<strong>in</strong>ed market power to negotiate with bus<strong>in</strong>esses on these customers’ behalf, while at<br />

the same time protect<strong>in</strong>g consumer privacy (Hagel & S<strong>in</strong>ger, 1999). Accord<strong>in</strong>gly,<br />

customers would receive a privacy tool kit provid<strong>in</strong>g them with an anonymous email<br />

address and filter<strong>in</strong>g technology to block unauthorized vendors. Customers would use an<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary-issued credit card, allow<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>fomediary to track all of the customer’s<br />

onl<strong>in</strong>e and offl<strong>in</strong>e purchases, and to create a detailed personal profile of their purchas<strong>in</strong>g<br />

behaviors. This anonymous payment mechanism would also prevents vendors from<br />

access<strong>in</strong>g personal data (Hagel & S<strong>in</strong>ger, 1999).<br />

By perform<strong>in</strong>g searches for the customer, the <strong>in</strong>fomediary would alleviate<br />

problems of <strong>in</strong>formation overload. If a customer wanted a specific product, the<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary would solicits bids from vendors by literally commodify<strong>in</strong>g the customer’s<br />

personal <strong>in</strong>formation and sell<strong>in</strong>g it to prospective vendors. To protect the customer’s<br />

privacy, the transaction would be carried out anonymously, us<strong>in</strong>g email and targeted<br />

66


market<strong>in</strong>g. Assured of their security and privacy, <strong>in</strong>dividuals would welcome this targeted<br />

market<strong>in</strong>g (J. E. Campbell & Carlson, 2002; Downes & Mui, 1998; Hagel & S<strong>in</strong>ger, 1999).<br />

Under this system, both the <strong>in</strong>fomediary and the customers would profit from the<br />

sale of personal <strong>in</strong>formation. For the consumer, the basic cost of membership—<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the privacy and profil<strong>in</strong>g services—would be free, and customers would pay a 2 ½ percent<br />

agency fee when purchas<strong>in</strong>g products through the <strong>in</strong>fomediary. However, they would<br />

receive a portion of the vendor’s payment for access<strong>in</strong>g their <strong>in</strong>formation profiles. Hagel<br />

and S<strong>in</strong>ger estimate that, by reveal<strong>in</strong>g their <strong>in</strong>formation, a household would save<br />

approximately $1,400 per year through lower purchase prices and payments (Hagel &<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ger, 1999).<br />

Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger contend that their <strong>in</strong>fomediary model creates value not only for<br />

consumers but also for bus<strong>in</strong>esses. For, while customers have lower transaction costs and<br />

reduced uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties, bus<strong>in</strong>esses benefit by obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g direct access to <strong>in</strong>terested<br />

customers. For example, currently, 98 percent of customers ignore market<strong>in</strong>g messages<br />

such as pop-up ads and spam. By offer<strong>in</strong>g vendors direct access to customers that are<br />

known to be <strong>in</strong>terested, bus<strong>in</strong>esses can save money through higher response rates, which<br />

<strong>in</strong> turn <strong>in</strong>crease the value of the customer <strong>in</strong>formation (Hagel & S<strong>in</strong>ger, 1999).<br />

As we have seen from the previous chapter, for an <strong>in</strong>termediary to achieve a<br />

critical mass, customers must be able to trust them. Thus, to ga<strong>in</strong> this trust, the<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary must be “customer-fac<strong>in</strong>g” and not “vendor-fac<strong>in</strong>g”. Customers must trust<br />

67


the <strong>in</strong>fomediary to prevent unauthorized access and abuse of their personal <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

(Hagel & S<strong>in</strong>ger, 1999). The <strong>in</strong>fomediary would need to build trust through reputation<br />

and a positive feedback cycle, whereby it would then achieve market dom<strong>in</strong>ance and<br />

susta<strong>in</strong>ed growth.<br />

To help achieve market dom<strong>in</strong>ance, Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s <strong>in</strong>fomediary model would<br />

take advantage of <strong>in</strong>formation commodities. Although <strong>in</strong>fomediaries can operate <strong>in</strong> any<br />

market, their prospects are greatest <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation markets where market failures tend to<br />

generate high transaction costs. Thus, products and services with a high content of<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation, such as computer goods, mortgages and telecommunications services offer<br />

good opportunities for <strong>in</strong>fomediaries (Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger, 1999, 53). Because <strong>in</strong>fomediaries<br />

would operate over the Internet, consumers would benefit from the <strong>in</strong>fomediaries’<br />

capacity to search for and bundle <strong>in</strong>formation goods.<br />

Infomediaries <strong>in</strong> practice<br />

Shortly after the release of Net Worth <strong>in</strong> 1999, several new companies that used<br />

Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s <strong>in</strong>fomediary model emerged. These newcomers <strong>in</strong>cluded Lumeria,<br />

Privaseek, AllAdvantage, Firefly, PrivacyBank.com, Popular Demand and Enonymous.<br />

Three of these cases are discussed briefly below.<br />

68


i. Lumeria<br />

In 1999, Lumeria was poised to become the most successful of the new<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary bus<strong>in</strong>esses. Lumeria was founded on the pr<strong>in</strong>ciple that a customer’s personal<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation must be safely guarded, yet easily accessible and anonymously shared with<br />

others (Lumeria Inc., 2000b). In keep<strong>in</strong>g with Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s model, Lumeria adopted<br />

a “customer-fac<strong>in</strong>g” strategy. Customers stored data <strong>in</strong> a “SuperProfile,” giv<strong>in</strong>g Lumeria<br />

permission to sell that <strong>in</strong>formation to a network of vendors. The vendors could then<br />

perform highly targeted, permission-based market<strong>in</strong>g to those people who had expressed<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> the merchandise. Vendor fees would be paid directly to consumers, with<br />

Lumeria tak<strong>in</strong>g a small percentage (Lester, March 2001; Lumeria Inc., 2000b).<br />

Closely follow<strong>in</strong>g Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s plan with its “Sunsh<strong>in</strong>e Platform”<br />

technology, Lumeria promised to “dramatically improve the security, efficiencies, and<br />

effectiveness of any onl<strong>in</strong>e transaction, whether for commerce or content, for bus<strong>in</strong>ess or<br />

for <strong>in</strong>dividuals,” (Lumeria Inc., 2000a). The Sunsh<strong>in</strong>e technology offered the follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

services:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Privacy and Cookie Agent—protects user’s identity by hid<strong>in</strong>g their IP address<br />

and manag<strong>in</strong>g cookies.<br />

Form-Filler/e-Wallet—allows forms to be filled-out and secure purchases to<br />

be made based on data <strong>in</strong> the user’s profile.<br />

Content Filter<strong>in</strong>g Agent—allows user-specific pop-up w<strong>in</strong>dows or other<br />

content add-<strong>in</strong>s to appear on web pages. It also provides a method for<br />

replac<strong>in</strong>g web banner ads accord<strong>in</strong>g to each user’s profile.<br />

XML Standards—promotes creation of XML by web developers, thus<br />

support<strong>in</strong>g aggregated personal profil<strong>in</strong>g of customers. (Lumeria Inc., 2000a)<br />

69


In the words of Lumeria’s founder, Fred Davis, “basically, we created a new piece<br />

of Internet <strong>in</strong>frastructure for the secure communication and authentication of<br />

transmissions across the Internet. It took us a few years and millions of dollars to develop<br />

it, but now it's here, and it's pretty cool,”(Lester, March 2001). Unfortunately, Lumeria<br />

was not cool enough. As of 2002, Fred Davis was seek<strong>in</strong>g a buyer for the company<br />

(Delevett, 2002, February 19).<br />

ii. AllAdvantage 12<br />

Another onl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>fomediary, AllAdvantage, also followed Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s plan.<br />

Launched <strong>in</strong> March 30, 1999, AllAdvantage allowed <strong>in</strong>dividuals to sell their attention and<br />

personal <strong>in</strong>formation to advertisers while ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g their personal privacy. To<br />

accomplish this, AllAdvantage provided a software program —the “ViewBar”—that<br />

allowed customers to view targeted advertisements on their personal computers.<br />

AllAdvantage paid customers fifty cents and hour (up to forty hours per month) for<br />

view<strong>in</strong>g the advertisements, while bus<strong>in</strong>esses paid AllAdvantage for this targeted<br />

advertis<strong>in</strong>g opportunity. To <strong>in</strong>crease participation and build a critical mass, AllAdvantage<br />

encouraged its members to make referrals. For example, it paid its members small fees<br />

(based on a descend<strong>in</strong>g scale of four levels) for the time that a referral, or referral of a<br />

referral, etc., spent search<strong>in</strong>g the web. In addition to its advertis<strong>in</strong>g fees, AllAdvantage<br />

70


<strong>in</strong>tended to capitalize on the <strong>in</strong>formation stored <strong>in</strong> members’ browsers, which<br />

documented keyword searches and sites visited. By exploit<strong>in</strong>g this <strong>in</strong>formation,<br />

AllAdvantage could better target ads, and thus charge a premium for advertis<strong>in</strong>g space<br />

(Beal, 2002).<br />

Although AllAdvantage successfully generated a critical mass, the overall bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

model was unsuccessful. In 2000, AllAdvantage grew exponentially <strong>in</strong> popularity and<br />

membership rates. With<strong>in</strong> five months of its launch<strong>in</strong>g, 10,000 to 20,000 members signed<br />

on each day. By July of 2000, total membership to AllAdvantage surpassed seven million<br />

(Beal, 2002). Nonetheless, problems mounted. As AllAdvantage’s founder, Jim<br />

Jorgenson, expla<strong>in</strong>ed, “It was a chicken and egg problem,” (Beal, 2002). Because the<br />

market for targeted advertis<strong>in</strong>g was still young, few bus<strong>in</strong>esses were ready to subscribe to<br />

AllAdvantage’s service. Furthermore, due to software constra<strong>in</strong>ts, only 2 to 3 percent of<br />

the ads were actually targeted to members. Another fatal flaw <strong>in</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess model was<br />

customer behavior. Receiv<strong>in</strong>g money for merely look<strong>in</strong>g, most members did just that—<br />

only rarely did they purchase the advertised merchandise. Some even blocked the ads on<br />

their computer screen with duct tape. As a result, AllAdvantage was unable to add value<br />

for their advertisers. Moreover, they were obliged to pay members, regardless of whether<br />

12 The follow<strong>in</strong>g is a summary from Brent D. Beal’s report entitled AllAdvantage.com: an Internet Infomediary<br />

(2002).<br />

71


or not they sold advertis<strong>in</strong>g space. Because membership rates were so high, payments to<br />

members reached the millions, and AllAdvantage quickly burned through its <strong>in</strong>vestor<br />

money. In the wake of the dot.com crash, funds disappeared, and AllAdvantage folded<br />

(Beal, 2002).<br />

iii. Firefly/Passport<br />

A third <strong>in</strong>fomediary, Firefly, predates Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s <strong>in</strong>fomediary plan. Firefly<br />

began <strong>in</strong> 1995 as a program called Helpful Onl<strong>in</strong>e Music Recommendations (HOMR),<br />

us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>telligent software to recommend music and bands (Oakes, 1999, August 12a).<br />

Later, Firefly developed an <strong>in</strong>fomediary service called “Passport”, which collected<br />

demographic and psychographic <strong>in</strong>formation from consumers. Passport also used<br />

customer <strong>in</strong>formation to offer personalized suggestions and reviews on items of <strong>in</strong>terest<br />

(Kannan, Chang, & Wh<strong>in</strong>ston, 2001).<br />

In 1998, Microsoft acquired Passport so it could bundle the software with its XP<br />

operat<strong>in</strong>g system and accelerate the delivery of its privacy-enhanc<strong>in</strong>g services. Microsoft’s<br />

Passport Wallet, which collected a user’s credit card and password <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> a<br />

database, was designed to simplify e-commerce transactions. However, the purchase met<br />

opposition from privacy advocates who accused Microsoft of becom<strong>in</strong>g “Big Brother,”<br />

and try<strong>in</strong>g to control customer profile databases (Luen<strong>in</strong>g, 1998).<br />

Then, <strong>in</strong> October of 2001, the Passport software exhibited a serious flaw, which<br />

would expose users’ password, credit card <strong>in</strong>formation and other personal data<br />

72


(McWilliams, November 2, 2001). In 2001, privacy advocates filed a compla<strong>in</strong>t with the<br />

FTC, claim<strong>in</strong>g that Microsoft’s Passport had threatened the privacy of the 100 million<br />

users by deceptively collect<strong>in</strong>g consumer <strong>in</strong>formation (Manjoo, August 16, 2001). In<br />

2002, Microsoft settled the charges with the FTC. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the compla<strong>in</strong>t settlement,<br />

Microsoft had falsely represented that:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

It employs reasonable and appropriate measures under the circumstances to<br />

ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> and protect the privacy and confidentiality of consumers' personal<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation collected through its Passport and Passport Wallet services,<br />

<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g credit card numbers and bill<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation stored <strong>in</strong> Passport<br />

Wallet;<br />

Purchases made with Passport Wallet are generally safer or more secure than<br />

purchases made at the same site without Passport Wallet when, <strong>in</strong> fact, most<br />

consumers received identical security at those sites regardless of whether they<br />

used Passport Wallet to complete their transactions;<br />

Passport did not collect any personally identifiable <strong>in</strong>formation other than that<br />

described <strong>in</strong> its privacy policy when, <strong>in</strong> fact, Passport collected and held, for a<br />

limited time, a personally identifiable sign-<strong>in</strong> history for each user. (Federal<br />

Trade Commission, August 8, 2002)<br />

Passport software is still available for Microsoft users, but the security and privacy<br />

flaws have prompted many users to opt out of its services. The case illustrates that, even<br />

for companies that have tremendous resources at their disposal, the <strong>in</strong>fomediary model<br />

has some <strong>in</strong>herent flaws.<br />

Shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs of <strong>in</strong>fomediaries<br />

Notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g the myriad uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong> the digital age, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries built<br />

along the l<strong>in</strong>es of Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s model have yet to succeed. The NASDAQ crash of<br />

73


2000 and the subsequent withdraw of <strong>in</strong>vestments from e-commerce contributed to the<br />

demise of Lumeria and AllAdvantage. But equally, if not more, important was the fact<br />

that a large majority of bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers rejected these privacy-based<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary bus<strong>in</strong>ess models (Bodorik & Jutla, 2003). As we have seen <strong>in</strong> chapter four, a<br />

successful <strong>in</strong>fomediary must follow seven rules for success. Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s model<br />

followed two of these rules: it took advantage of <strong>in</strong>formation commodities and helped<br />

organize and bundle large amounts of <strong>in</strong>formation, and it attempted to offer consumers<br />

advice on e-commerce purchases <strong>in</strong> specialized <strong>in</strong>dustries. As described below, by<br />

neglect<strong>in</strong>g five of the seven rules, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries failed to reduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties for<br />

consumers and bus<strong>in</strong>esses.<br />

1. Provide value for consumers and bus<strong>in</strong>esses<br />

Infomediaries did not provide value for both bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers. For<br />

customers to trust <strong>in</strong>fomediaries with their personal <strong>in</strong>formation, the <strong>in</strong>fomediaries must<br />

be totally “customer fac<strong>in</strong>g” (Lev<strong>in</strong>, 1999). However, by focus<strong>in</strong>g on consumers almost<br />

exclusively, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries were unable to provide enough value for bus<strong>in</strong>esses. To make a<br />

profit, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries must have the participation of a vast network of bus<strong>in</strong>esses. But<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>esses will only participate given a significant positive net ga<strong>in</strong>. Moreover, an<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary must be more efficient than bus<strong>in</strong>esses that act <strong>in</strong>dependently to br<strong>in</strong>g buyers<br />

and sellers together. In the case of AllAdvantage, bus<strong>in</strong>esses did not benefit from targeted<br />

advertisements to <strong>in</strong>terested customers, lead<strong>in</strong>g to its failure (Chen, Ganesh, &<br />

74


Padmanabhan, Fall 2002; Oakes, 1999, August 12b). In some cases, work<strong>in</strong>g through an<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary can decrease net ga<strong>in</strong>s for bus<strong>in</strong>esses. With direct access to an <strong>in</strong>creased<br />

number of customers, bus<strong>in</strong>esses can poach on their competitors’ customers. Thus,<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediaries can unravel, mean<strong>in</strong>g that no bus<strong>in</strong>ess will ga<strong>in</strong> a net profit from jo<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g,<br />

even if the access is free (Chen et al., Fall 2002).<br />

2. Promote trust <strong>in</strong> onl<strong>in</strong>e transactions<br />

The <strong>in</strong>fomediary’s <strong>in</strong>ability to establish a high level of trust also helped to account<br />

for the model’s failure. Although the <strong>in</strong>fomediary is a third party, there are no guarantees<br />

that it will be a ‘trustworthy’ third party (Shear<strong>in</strong> & Maes, no date). Especially <strong>in</strong> a rapidly<br />

chang<strong>in</strong>g e-commerce environment, <strong>in</strong> which most companies are unstable, consumers are<br />

unlikely to trust so much personal <strong>in</strong>formation to any company, third party or not (Muller,<br />

2000). For example, customers who <strong>in</strong>vested time creat<strong>in</strong>g profiles on Lumeria must be<br />

wonder<strong>in</strong>g now what has become of their personal <strong>in</strong>formation. Thus, unless consumers<br />

are offered substantial benefits for reveal<strong>in</strong>g their personal <strong>in</strong>formation, they will be<br />

uncomfortable with computer programs track<strong>in</strong>g their every move, and unwill<strong>in</strong>g to<br />

transact through a s<strong>in</strong>gle <strong>in</strong>fomediary (Bodorik & Jutla, 2003; "The rise of the<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary," 1999, June 24; Vora, December 1999).<br />

3. Respect <strong>in</strong>formation privacy<br />

Ironically, although <strong>in</strong>fomediaries were conceived to protect <strong>in</strong>dividual privacy,<br />

they ultimately generated additional privacy concerns (Dix, no date). Controll<strong>in</strong>g personal<br />

75


<strong>in</strong>formation, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries determ<strong>in</strong>e the perceived level of privacy. And how can<br />

consumers be one hundred percent certa<strong>in</strong> that these agents will act entirely on their<br />

behalf? As the case of Microsoft’s Passport illustrates, once such comprehensive personal<br />

profiles have been put together, there is a significant risk of malicious misuse by the<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary or an outside agent (Bodorik & Jutla, 2003).<br />

4 & 5. Achieve critical mass, and ga<strong>in</strong> a first-mover advantage<br />

As we have seen <strong>in</strong> chapter four, network effects are essential to an <strong>in</strong>fomediary’s<br />

success. Although Lumeria heeded many rules for success, it failed to achieve a critical<br />

mass of users and a first mover advantage, so it could not susta<strong>in</strong> its efforts. In contrast,<br />

AllAdvantage achieved a critical mass of users, but the expense <strong>in</strong>volved, together with<br />

the fragile economic environment of 2000, caused it to lose its edge. AllAdvantage also<br />

failed to take advantage of positive network effects to the detriment of its vendor<br />

network. Unable to properly analyze its customers’ brows<strong>in</strong>g and purchas<strong>in</strong>g records, the<br />

company could not <strong>in</strong>fer needs and preferences for the benefit of its vendors (Vora,<br />

December 1999).<br />

These failures to ga<strong>in</strong> a critical mass raise the question of who is better suited to<br />

become an <strong>in</strong>fomediary: a startup company or an <strong>in</strong>cumbent. Newcomers must conv<strong>in</strong>ce<br />

millions of consumers to jo<strong>in</strong>, promis<strong>in</strong>g them benefits down the road. Given their<br />

exist<strong>in</strong>g customer database and a critical mass of customers, exist<strong>in</strong>g companies might<br />

have better luck. But here<strong>in</strong> is the paradox. An exist<strong>in</strong>g company is unlikely to be a<br />

76


successful <strong>in</strong>fomediary, because customers would be wary that the company would act on<br />

its own behalf. Even if a startup <strong>in</strong>fomediary were to form a jo<strong>in</strong>t venture with an exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

company, it would not likely solve the problem of trust. If the <strong>in</strong>fomediary ran <strong>in</strong>to<br />

f<strong>in</strong>ancial trouble, there would be no guarantees to prevent the sale of personal <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

to un-trusted third parties (Hagel & S<strong>in</strong>ger, 1999; Muller, 2000; Rosenblatt, July 1999).<br />

The case studies described above suggest that the bus<strong>in</strong>ess model of the<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary is not f<strong>in</strong>ancially viable. The authors of the plan estimated that an<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary based on a jo<strong>in</strong>t venture would require an up-front <strong>in</strong>vestment of $380<br />

million. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to their estimates, positive returns could be expected <strong>in</strong> the eighth<br />

year, with revenues of $5 billion by the tenth year. These high fixed costs and low profit<br />

marg<strong>in</strong>s are unattractive to venture capitalists, who want to see more immediate returns<br />

on their <strong>in</strong>vestments. Even Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger admit that for a startup company, the<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment would be significantly more (Hagel & S<strong>in</strong>ger, 1999; Muller, 2000; Rosenblatt,<br />

July 1999).<br />

Alternatives<br />

Although no company has yet to develop a successful <strong>in</strong>fomediary on the order<br />

conceived by Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger, more modest versions of <strong>in</strong>fomediaries, tak<strong>in</strong>g the form<br />

of search eng<strong>in</strong>es, communities of <strong>in</strong>terest, and corporate sites, do exist (Grover & Teng,<br />

2001). Amazon.com, eBay, Expedia.com and PriceL<strong>in</strong>e.com are forms of <strong>in</strong>fomediaries.<br />

They work to reduce search costs and uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties associated with e-commerce. The<br />

77


ma<strong>in</strong> difference between these digital <strong>in</strong>termediaries and Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s <strong>in</strong>fomediary is<br />

that the latter do not deal with digitally related uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties by commodify<strong>in</strong>g consumer<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation and privacy. Rather, these companies succeed because they establish a social<br />

contract with their customers. Social contracts def<strong>in</strong>e collective privacy policies that e-<br />

commerce bus<strong>in</strong>esses adhere to, and they constra<strong>in</strong> the behavior of companies while<br />

protect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividuals (Kaufman & Powers, 2002).<br />

i. eBay<br />

eBay, the largest Internet auction site, exemplifies a successful <strong>in</strong>fomediary.<br />

Unlike the physical auction houses of the 19 th century, eBay br<strong>in</strong>gs buyers and sellers<br />

together <strong>in</strong> cyberspace, allow<strong>in</strong>g millions of goods to be auctioned off simultaneously. It<br />

does not act as a pr<strong>in</strong>cipal, because it has no ownership <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> the goods sold. As an<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary, its only <strong>in</strong>terests are to protect the <strong>in</strong>tegrity of the onl<strong>in</strong>e auction process by<br />

provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation l<strong>in</strong>ks. eBay profits by charg<strong>in</strong>g fees to list items, and collect<strong>in</strong>g a<br />

percentage of the profit of transactions (Bunnell & Luecke, 2000).<br />

Although eBay was not the first onl<strong>in</strong>e auction site, it was the first to achieve<br />

critical mass, captur<strong>in</strong>g a dom<strong>in</strong>ant share of buyers and sellers. By achiev<strong>in</strong>g critical mass,<br />

it ga<strong>in</strong>ed the first-mover advantage necessary for success. Thus, eBay benefits from<br />

positive network effects, because each additional member benefits both buyers and sellers<br />

(Bunnell & Luecke, 2000).<br />

78


By outsourc<strong>in</strong>g some of its core services, eBay ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>s a vertically dis<strong>in</strong>tegrated<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess model. The most important outsourced activity, web host<strong>in</strong>g, is assigned to<br />

AboveNet and Exodus <strong>Communication</strong>s. In addition, eBay ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>s relationships with<br />

PayPal, its preferred secured payment service, and Mailboxes Etc., which provides a 10-15<br />

percent discount for eBay users. By rely<strong>in</strong>g on others to perform these key tasks, eBay<br />

can focus on its core bus<strong>in</strong>ess practices (Bunnell & Luecke, 2000).<br />

eBay’s culture has served to enhance an image of trustworth<strong>in</strong>ess. eBay was<br />

founded on core values of honesty, openness, equality, empowerment, trust, mutual<br />

respect and mutual responsibility. This foundation has prevented it from becom<strong>in</strong>g<br />

opportunistic, decreas<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties for its members (Bunnell & Luecke, 2000). In<br />

onl<strong>in</strong>e transactions, trust is established through ‘feedback’—reviews submitted by buyers<br />

and sellers, vouch<strong>in</strong>g for the quality of the product, ease of payment process<strong>in</strong>g and arrival<br />

time of the good purchased.<br />

Nonetheless, eBay’s trusted system is subject to fraud, rais<strong>in</strong>g concerns about<br />

eBay’s validity as a model <strong>in</strong>fomediary. With computer technologies, it is easy to cheat on<br />

the Internet, so onl<strong>in</strong>e companies must cont<strong>in</strong>uously struggle to keep sw<strong>in</strong>dlers at bay. In<br />

fact, accord<strong>in</strong>g to the Federal Trade Commission, onl<strong>in</strong>e auction frauds are more<br />

prevalent than any other type of onl<strong>in</strong>e fraud. In 2003, they accounted for 48 percent of<br />

all fraud compla<strong>in</strong>ts filed (Krebs, January 23, 2004). Yet eBay itself claims that only one-<br />

79


hundredth of one percent of the 20 million items that it lists at any given time are<br />

fraudulent (Hafner, March 20, 2004).<br />

To cope with the possibility of fraud, eBay complements the feedback system,<br />

act<strong>in</strong>g as its own <strong>in</strong>termediary to build trust and provide protection. To this end, eBay<br />

takes the follow<strong>in</strong>g security measures:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

fraud protection service<br />

escrow service for buyers to exam<strong>in</strong>e items before mak<strong>in</strong>g<br />

payments<br />

Verification of seller identities<br />

Independent appraisal services<br />

Protection aga<strong>in</strong>st non-pay<strong>in</strong>g bidders<br />

Dispute-resolution and mediation services<br />

Anti-fraud <strong>in</strong>vestigation and enforcement. (Swire, 2002)<br />

Although eBay began as a person-to-person channel of exchange, small bus<strong>in</strong>esses<br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly use its services to attract customers. In 2000, an estimated eighty percent of<br />

eBay’s revenues were generated by twenty percent of its users, most of which are<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>esses us<strong>in</strong>g the site as a portal to their own website. Thus, by simplify<strong>in</strong>g the search<br />

and transaction process, eBay benefits bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers (Bunnell & Luecke,<br />

2000).<br />

To address privacy concerns, eBay adheres to a strict privacy policy. It does not<br />

sell or rent personal <strong>in</strong>formation to other bus<strong>in</strong>esses without explicit consent of its<br />

members (eBay, 2004). The <strong>in</strong>formation that eBay does collect allows the company to<br />

customize its services. Thus, eBay uses cookies to track web flow, measure promotional<br />

80


effectiveness, and promote trust and safety. It aggregates personal <strong>in</strong>formation and<br />

discloses it to advertisers and third parties for market<strong>in</strong>g and promotional purposes.<br />

However, this <strong>in</strong>formation is disclosed <strong>in</strong> a way that precludes any personal identification<br />

(eBay, 2004). By form<strong>in</strong>g privacy-based social contracts with its members, eBay has<br />

decreased the uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties entailed <strong>in</strong> e-commerce.<br />

ii. Amazon.com<br />

Amazon.com, “the earth’s largest bookstore,” is another example of a successful<br />

digital-age <strong>in</strong>fomediary. Some refer to Amazon.com as an example of dis<strong>in</strong>termediation,<br />

because it allows customers to bypass traditional brick-and-mortar bookstores to purchase<br />

books onl<strong>in</strong>e. But Amazon.com does not dis<strong>in</strong>termediate—it does not produce books, it<br />

only distributes them. Amazon.com.com is <strong>in</strong> fact an <strong>in</strong>termediary, br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g buyers and<br />

sellers together, establish<strong>in</strong>g trust and reduc<strong>in</strong>g search costs associated with e-commerce.<br />

To support its activities, Amazon.com embeds filter<strong>in</strong>g technology that enables<br />

personalized recommendations to be shown based on buy and search history, thus<br />

digitiz<strong>in</strong>g its expertise <strong>in</strong> the book market (Chircu & Kauffman, 2001; A. L. Shapiro,<br />

1999).<br />

Amazon.com benefits handsomely from its first mover advantage, which <strong>in</strong> turn<br />

provides positive network effects. As more users participate, everyone benefits from<br />

Amazon.com’s search functions, recommendations, and user reviews. Amazon.com’s<br />

first-mover advantage has allowed it to amass market value over thirty times that of<br />

81


BarnesandNoble.com (Chircu & Kauffman, 2001). This market dom<strong>in</strong>ance has enabled<br />

Amazon.com to expand its selection to music and merchandise as well.<br />

Like eBay, Amazon.com vertically dis<strong>in</strong>tegrated by form<strong>in</strong>g partnerships and<br />

alliances with other firms. Amazon.com follows three bus<strong>in</strong>ess models: retailer, a<br />

platform provider for other retailers (such as Circuit City) and an auction marketplace. It<br />

forms partnerships with manufacturers (such as the Disney Store), smaller bus<strong>in</strong>esses and<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividual sellers (E-Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Strategies, 2001, October). Furthermore, Amazon.com<br />

employs other companies to perform functions such as shipp<strong>in</strong>g, fill<strong>in</strong>g orders, analysis,<br />

market<strong>in</strong>g, process<strong>in</strong>g payments and customer service (Amazon.com, 2004)<br />

Amazon.com is a trusted web merchant, build<strong>in</strong>g a reputation through brand<strong>in</strong>g<br />

and service. In fact, consumers trust Amazon.com so much that they frequently buy from<br />

the site even when it does not have the lowest prices, confirm<strong>in</strong>g the importance of trust<br />

<strong>in</strong> e-commerce (M. D. Smith et al., 2000). Yet Amazon.com ran <strong>in</strong>to trouble <strong>in</strong> 1999<br />

when the public discovered that publishers were pay<strong>in</strong>g more than $10,000 to have their<br />

books featured with accolades such as “New and Notable” and “Dest<strong>in</strong>ed for Greatness.”<br />

By allow<strong>in</strong>g publishers to pay for placement, Amazon.com put the needs of the publisher<br />

above the consumer. Customers lost faith <strong>in</strong> the site as a result. To overcome the<br />

problem, Amazon.com quickly changed its policy, promis<strong>in</strong>g to disclose when publishers<br />

had paid for placement. Still, the <strong>in</strong>cident unfavorably affected the perceived level of trust<br />

<strong>in</strong> Amazon.com as an unbiased <strong>in</strong>termediary (A. L. Shapiro, 1999).<br />

82


Like eBay, Amazon.com adheres to a strict privacy policy based on social<br />

contracts. Amazon.com uses cookies to track <strong>in</strong>formation about its customers, us<strong>in</strong>g this<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation to personalize the shopp<strong>in</strong>g experience by recommend<strong>in</strong>g future purchases,<br />

one-click purchas<strong>in</strong>g, personalized greet<strong>in</strong>gs, wish lists and shopp<strong>in</strong>g carts. Amazon.com<br />

does not sell personal <strong>in</strong>formation to other bus<strong>in</strong>esses, but it does share its customer<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation with its subsidiaries (Amazon.com, 2004). Consumers do not m<strong>in</strong>d that<br />

Amazon.com collects <strong>in</strong>formation, because it allows the site to offer personalized<br />

recommendations.<br />

Conclusion<br />

Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger laid out a complex model for <strong>in</strong>fomediaries <strong>in</strong> their book Net<br />

Worth: Shap<strong>in</strong>g Markets When Customers Make the Rules. Their bus<strong>in</strong>ess plan attempted to<br />

resolve many uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties of the digital age: <strong>in</strong>formation overload, <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

asymmetry, privacy concerns, consumer data collection and trust <strong>in</strong> e-commerce. By<br />

controll<strong>in</strong>g and aggregat<strong>in</strong>g personal consumer <strong>in</strong>formation, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries commodified<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation privacy. Consumers then sold their personal <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> exchange for<br />

targeted market<strong>in</strong>g messages from approved vendors. At the same time, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries<br />

used the consumer <strong>in</strong>formation profiles to make recommendations and anticipate the<br />

needs of their customers.<br />

In 1999, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries were the ‘next big th<strong>in</strong>g’ <strong>in</strong> e-commerce. Companies such<br />

as Lumeria, AllAdvantage and Passport closely followed Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s plan. Yet, no<br />

83


<strong>in</strong>fomediaries created after the release of Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s book still exist today.<br />

Although Passport, now owned by Microsoft, is still function<strong>in</strong>g, it faces serious<br />

allegations over the misuse and violation of personal consumer <strong>in</strong>formation.<br />

There are several reasons for the failure of <strong>in</strong>fomediaries. First, Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger<br />

<strong>in</strong>troduced their bus<strong>in</strong>ess plan before the dot.com bubble burst. Investors clamored to<br />

s<strong>in</strong>k money <strong>in</strong>to potential e-commerce companies. The demise of AllAdvantage and<br />

Lumeria corresponds with the crash of the stock market, signal<strong>in</strong>g that it may have been<br />

bad tim<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Second, <strong>in</strong> plac<strong>in</strong>g so much value on the consumer, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries failed to create<br />

enough value for the bus<strong>in</strong>ess. This lack of balance was especially evident <strong>in</strong> the case of<br />

AllAdvantage; its bus<strong>in</strong>ess plan unraveled when bus<strong>in</strong>esses became disaffected, and the<br />

company still had to pay millions of dollars to their customers. As we saw <strong>in</strong> chapters<br />

Three and Four, an <strong>in</strong>termediary performs best when it meets both bus<strong>in</strong>ess and<br />

consumer needs equally.<br />

Third, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries failed to garner enough trust from their customers. A high<br />

level of trust is crucial <strong>in</strong> e-commerce, as without it transaction and agency costs are too<br />

great to susta<strong>in</strong> a market. However, the benefits of hav<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>fomediary did not<br />

outweigh the risk entailed <strong>in</strong> reveal<strong>in</strong>g personal <strong>in</strong>formation. In Lumeria’s case, customers<br />

were unwill<strong>in</strong>g to trust an unknown company to handle all of their private <strong>in</strong>formation.<br />

84


Fourth, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries overestimated their ability to reduce privacy concerns <strong>in</strong> e-<br />

commerce. They failed to take <strong>in</strong>to account the fact that consumers desired a perceived<br />

level of control over their own personal <strong>in</strong>formation, and that entrust<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

to an <strong>in</strong>fomediary did not equate with control. This problem suggests that <strong>in</strong>fomediaries<br />

cannot resolve uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties relat<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>formation privacy. Rather, privacy concerns<br />

should be resolved through transparent privacy policies and social contracts.<br />

Fifth, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries failed to take <strong>in</strong>to account key aspects of a networked<br />

economy. To succeed, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries needed a critical mass of users and a first-mover<br />

advantage. Without a critical mass, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries, most notably Lumeria, could not<br />

susta<strong>in</strong> their high fixed costs. Although AllAdvantage had a critical mass of users, it was<br />

unable to take advantage of the ensu<strong>in</strong>g network effects.<br />

The failure of Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s <strong>in</strong>fomediary plan does not suggest that all<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediaries are doomed. In fact, several <strong>in</strong>fomediaries have emerged <strong>in</strong> recent years to<br />

become dom<strong>in</strong>ant market players. eBay and Amazon.com are most notable <strong>in</strong> this regard.<br />

Shunn<strong>in</strong>g the personal <strong>in</strong>formation and privacy bus<strong>in</strong>ess, these companies are remarkably<br />

dist<strong>in</strong>ct from the model bus<strong>in</strong>ess proposed by Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger. They are <strong>in</strong>termediaries<br />

<strong>in</strong> a more traditional sense— br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g buyers and sellers together, stepp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> to reduce<br />

search costs, transaction costs, <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry and <strong>in</strong>formation overload <strong>in</strong> e-<br />

commerce. They have succeeded by adher<strong>in</strong>g to the seven rules of success for digital age<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries. They resolve tensions <strong>in</strong> consumer <strong>in</strong>formation collection and privacy by<br />

85


enter<strong>in</strong>g social contracts with their customers, thus restra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g tendencies for<br />

opportunism.<br />

86


Chapter 6. Conclusion<br />

Although privacy-based <strong>in</strong>fomediaries failed, evidence suggests that a market still<br />

exists for other types of <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> the digital age. This chapter summarizes the<br />

lessons learned and draws conclusions on the likelihood of consumer and bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

support for digital-age <strong>in</strong>termediaries. In addition, this chapter proposes further areas of<br />

research.<br />

This thesis sought to answer the follow<strong>in</strong>g question: Are there any circumstances under<br />

which an <strong>in</strong>termediary can succeed <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formation economy? It hypothesized that there is a role<br />

for <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> the digital age, but that <strong>in</strong>termediaries will only succeed as specialized<br />

agents for e-commerce, not as a solution for protect<strong>in</strong>g consumer <strong>in</strong>formation privacy.<br />

This thesis also questioned the failure of privacy- and personal <strong>in</strong>formation-controll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>fomediaries<br />

<strong>in</strong> the digital age. To account for the lack of supply for, and demand of, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries, this<br />

thesis hypothesized that the privacy-based <strong>in</strong>fomediary could not equally balance<br />

customer and bus<strong>in</strong>ess needs. Second, this thesis hypothesized that if they did not earn<br />

enough trust or confidence from consumers, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries would fail to achieve critical<br />

mass and first-mover advantage, two crucial elements for success <strong>in</strong> a networked<br />

economy.<br />

To test these hypotheses, this thesis proceeded as follows. Chapter Two<br />

developed a conceptual framework, focus<strong>in</strong>g on the fundamental role that <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

plays <strong>in</strong> an economic system. It def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>formation as an <strong>in</strong>tangible, non-exclusive, and<br />

87


non-rivalrous commodity, and emphasized the ability of <strong>in</strong>formation to reduce<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties as well as generate new ones. Furthermore, the chapter described how<br />

advances <strong>in</strong> technology affect the dissem<strong>in</strong>ation, use and commodification of <strong>in</strong>formation,<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry, and uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong> chang<strong>in</strong>g economic environments. Chapter<br />

Two presented two theories, agency theory and transaction cost theory, as a way of<br />

expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the roles uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry and how they can be reduced.<br />

An <strong>in</strong>termediary was def<strong>in</strong>ed as an agent that seeks to reduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties, transaction<br />

costs and agency costs when <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry is present. This chapter argued that,<br />

as technology advances, some uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties are resolved, but others emerge at the same<br />

time. Thus, the role of an <strong>in</strong>termediary depends on its ability to reduce the uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties<br />

that exist at any given po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> time. This phenomenon of <strong>in</strong>termediation-<br />

dis<strong>in</strong>termediation-re<strong>in</strong>termediation is essential to understand<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>termediary’s<br />

evolv<strong>in</strong>g role <strong>in</strong> historical and present-day markets (Chircu & Kauffman, 1998).<br />

Build<strong>in</strong>g on this conceptual framework, Chapter Three exam<strong>in</strong>ed the roles that<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries have played historically <strong>in</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties and transaction costs. It<br />

traces the evolution of <strong>in</strong>termediaries from traditional town markets to the <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

markets of the Industrial Revolution. In a town market centered on personal<br />

relationships, transaction costs and uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties were low, so <strong>in</strong>termediaries played a<br />

small role. Buyers and sellers relied <strong>in</strong>stead on trust and social contracts to solve<br />

problems of <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetry. Yet the advance of communication and<br />

88


transportation technologies gave rise to new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties, and <strong>in</strong>termediaries stepped <strong>in</strong><br />

to facilitate transactions over greater distances.<br />

With the advent of the Industrial Revolution, and the correspond<strong>in</strong>g<br />

improvements <strong>in</strong> communication and technology, bus<strong>in</strong>esses found new ways to organize<br />

themselves, eradicat<strong>in</strong>g the roles of certa<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>termediaries. To rema<strong>in</strong> viable,<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries had to re<strong>in</strong>vent themselves, tak<strong>in</strong>g on new roles <strong>in</strong> import<strong>in</strong>g, advertis<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

patents, and mass retail<strong>in</strong>g. As Chapter Three makes clear, <strong>in</strong>termediaries succeeded when<br />

they benefited both bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers, reduc<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties and transaction<br />

costs for both parties. This historical analysis confirms the cont<strong>in</strong>ual <strong>in</strong>termediation—<br />

dis<strong>in</strong>termediation—re<strong>in</strong>termediation cycle that <strong>in</strong>termediaries must follow to rema<strong>in</strong><br />

viable <strong>in</strong> chang<strong>in</strong>g economic and technological environments.<br />

Turn<strong>in</strong>g to the present, Chapter Four exam<strong>in</strong>ed the emerg<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties of the<br />

digital age. While <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the scope and speed of communication, the Internet and the<br />

World Wide Web <strong>in</strong>troduced at the same time new uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties, especially <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

asymmetry, <strong>in</strong>formation overload, privacy concerns, and trust. Just as <strong>in</strong> the Industrial<br />

Revolution, <strong>in</strong>termediaries stepped <strong>in</strong> to reduce uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, adapt<strong>in</strong>g themselves and<br />

<strong>in</strong>vent<strong>in</strong>g new roles. The analysis <strong>in</strong> this chapter reconfirmed how <strong>in</strong>termediaries follow<br />

an <strong>in</strong>termediation-dis<strong>in</strong>termediation-re<strong>in</strong>termediation cycle (Chircu & Kauffman, 1998).<br />

In this period, new types of <strong>in</strong>termediaries—<strong>in</strong>fomediaries—appeared to organize<br />

89


<strong>in</strong>formation-based digital markets, facilitat<strong>in</strong>g onl<strong>in</strong>e transactions and manag<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation overload.<br />

As Chapter Four made clear, <strong>in</strong>termediaries must not only re<strong>in</strong>vent their roles; to<br />

be viable <strong>in</strong>termediaries, they must provide a service that benefits both buyer and seller. If<br />

an <strong>in</strong>termediary’s behavior favors one party over another, it will lose its raison d’être.<br />

Keep<strong>in</strong>g this notion <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d, Chapter Four identified seven rules of success for digital-<br />

age <strong>in</strong>termediaries: 1) provide value for bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers; 2) promote trust <strong>in</strong><br />

onl<strong>in</strong>e transactions; 3) become experts <strong>in</strong> specialized <strong>in</strong>dustries; 4) respect <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

privacy; 5) achieve critical mass; 6) ga<strong>in</strong> first-mover advantage; and 7) take advantage of<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation commodities.<br />

Us<strong>in</strong>g these seven rules as criteria for evaluation, Chapter Five exam<strong>in</strong>ed the<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediary model laid out by John Hagel and Marc S<strong>in</strong>ger <strong>in</strong> their book Net Worth:<br />

Shap<strong>in</strong>g Markets When Customers Make the Rules, as well as three specific cases of<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediaries. Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger suggest that <strong>in</strong>fomediaries might provide a useful and<br />

lucrative service by aggregat<strong>in</strong>g customer <strong>in</strong>formation and act<strong>in</strong>g on behalf of the<br />

consumer <strong>in</strong> negotiations with bus<strong>in</strong>esses. Most importantly, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries would protect<br />

personal <strong>in</strong>formation, thus eas<strong>in</strong>g privacy concerns. Look<strong>in</strong>g at the <strong>in</strong>fomediary<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>esses Lumeria, AllAdvantage, and Passport, Chapter Five found that Hagel and<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ger’s model is unsusta<strong>in</strong>able. As the previous chapters suggested, and <strong>in</strong> accordance<br />

90


with the first hypothesis, <strong>in</strong>termediaries only succeed when they strike a balance between<br />

customers and bus<strong>in</strong>esses.<br />

This thesis also found support for the second hypothesis: the <strong>in</strong>fomediary model<br />

failed to account for the <strong>in</strong>herent aspects of a networked economy. As shown <strong>in</strong> Chapter<br />

Four, <strong>in</strong>fomediaries must achieve a critical mass and a first mover advantage to susta<strong>in</strong> a<br />

competitive edge and leverage their high sunk costs. Lumeria, the <strong>in</strong>fomediary that most<br />

closely followed Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s plan, did not acquire enough members to compensate<br />

for their high costs. On the other hand, AllAdvantage had the opposite problem. It<br />

achieved a critical mass so quickly that it could not susta<strong>in</strong> its “pay-to-click” bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

model. It did not have enough vendor support to cover the payments promised to its<br />

members.<br />

Significantly, the thesis also found that customers were unwill<strong>in</strong>g to trust all of<br />

their personal <strong>in</strong>formation to a s<strong>in</strong>gle source, and were thus unlikely to conduct all<br />

purchases through a s<strong>in</strong>gle <strong>in</strong>fomediary. These f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs support the third hypothesis:<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediaries failed to ga<strong>in</strong> consumer confidence. As we have seen <strong>in</strong> Chapters Two and<br />

Four, trust is crucial <strong>in</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g transaction and agency costs <strong>in</strong> both traditional and e-<br />

commerce bus<strong>in</strong>ess transactions.<br />

However, the failure of these <strong>in</strong>fomediaries does not suggest that<br />

dis<strong>in</strong>termediation is unlikely <strong>in</strong> the digital age. This thesis also exam<strong>in</strong>ed successful<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> e-commerce, notably eBay and Amazon.com. Both eBay and Amazon<br />

91


classify as “<strong>in</strong>fomediaries,” though not <strong>in</strong> the same sense as Hagel and S<strong>in</strong>ger’s<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediaries. They bundle and distribute large amounts of <strong>in</strong>formation goods, and offer<br />

expertise <strong>in</strong> specialized areas of e-commerce. They do not address privacy concerns by<br />

commodify<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation; rather, they engage <strong>in</strong> social contracts and display transparent<br />

privacy policies on their websites. Thus, by follow<strong>in</strong>g the seven rules presented <strong>in</strong><br />

Chapter Four, as Amazon.com and eBay do, digital <strong>in</strong>termediaries are likely to f<strong>in</strong>d<br />

acceptance from both consumers and bus<strong>in</strong>esses. These f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs support the f<strong>in</strong>al<br />

hypothesis: <strong>in</strong>termediaries will succeed as specialized agents to facilitate e-commerce by<br />

br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g buyers and sellers together and reduc<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs, uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation overload.<br />

Thus, there are circumstances under which an <strong>in</strong>termediary can succeed <strong>in</strong> the<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation economy. As we have seen <strong>in</strong> the conceptual framework and the historical<br />

analysis, <strong>in</strong>termediaries can succeed <strong>in</strong> any economy, so long as they solve the<br />

correspond<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties brought about by technological and economical advances. In<br />

the <strong>in</strong>formation economy, bus<strong>in</strong>esses and consumers will most likely enlist the services of<br />

an <strong>in</strong>termediary when they receive substantial benefits, and when they perceive the<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediary to be trustworthy. Likewise, <strong>in</strong>termediaries will most likely succeed if they<br />

build a critical mass of users, ga<strong>in</strong> a first-mover advantage and provide value to their<br />

customers. Above all, <strong>in</strong>termediaries must balance consumer and bus<strong>in</strong>ess needs equally.<br />

92


Suggested areas of research<br />

Bus<strong>in</strong>ess and policy solutions for <strong>in</strong>formation privacy<br />

Given the failure of <strong>in</strong>fomediaries to protect consumer <strong>in</strong>formation privacy, what<br />

other solutions might address this problem? Presently, no clear solution for privacy exists.<br />

In the digital age, we are <strong>in</strong> the midst of a radical reorganiz<strong>in</strong>g of bus<strong>in</strong>ess paradigms. We<br />

have yet to discover if the solution will be market-based or policy-based. Clearly, this area<br />

requires further exploration.<br />

One possible solution would be for the government to adopt a legal framework to<br />

facilitate e-commerce, impos<strong>in</strong>g stricter regulations on privacy violations and design<strong>in</strong>g<br />

best practices for bus<strong>in</strong>esses. In this scenario, the government would act as a trusted<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediary to <strong>in</strong>crease privacy protection (Bailey & Bakos, 1997; A. L. Shapiro, 1999).<br />

Another possible solution would be for bus<strong>in</strong>esses to implement self-regulated<br />

privacy policies. As we saw <strong>in</strong> the examples of Amazon.com and eBay, bus<strong>in</strong>esses do best<br />

when they make their privacy policies transparent, and offer the customer substantial<br />

benefits <strong>in</strong> return for the collection of personal <strong>in</strong>formation. Furthermore, bus<strong>in</strong>esses<br />

might engage <strong>in</strong> social contracts or procedural fairness. Further research may reveal the<br />

best solution to this problem.<br />

A market for privacy<br />

Another possible solution to privacy concerns <strong>in</strong> the digital age calls for the<br />

creation of a market for privacy. This market would give consumers control over their<br />

93


personal <strong>in</strong>formation, sell<strong>in</strong>g it for a price to <strong>in</strong>terested buyers. Given the failure of<br />

<strong>in</strong>fomediaries to oversee this type of market, who might step <strong>in</strong> to monitor this market?<br />

Is it likely to be government-controlled? Would a market for privacy really decrease<br />

transaction costs, or will the time and effort result <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>creased transaction costs?(A. L.<br />

Shapiro, 1999).<br />

Disadvantages of <strong>in</strong>termediaries<br />

This thesis explored the benefits of us<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>termediary for both consumers and<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>esses. <strong>Information</strong> <strong>in</strong>termediaries reduce <strong>in</strong>formation overload by filter<strong>in</strong>g and<br />

search<strong>in</strong>g, but <strong>in</strong> so do<strong>in</strong>g they potentially limit the user’s perspective. An <strong>in</strong>termediary<br />

may un<strong>in</strong>tentionally shelter the user from important <strong>in</strong>formation (A. L. Shapiro, 1999,<br />

112-114). This raises a f<strong>in</strong>al question: can us<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>termediary be disadvantageous, even<br />

if it seem<strong>in</strong>gly reduces transaction costs?<br />

94


References<br />

Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for "lemons": Quality uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and the market<br />

mechanism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 84 (No. 3), 488-500.<br />

Allen, B. (1990). <strong>Information</strong> as an economic commodity. The American Economic Review,<br />

Vol. 80 (No. 2, papers and proceed<strong>in</strong>gs of the hundred and second annual meet<strong>in</strong>g<br />

of the American Economic Association), 268-273.<br />

Amazon.com. (2004). Amazon.com privacy notice. Retrieved March 29, 2004, from<br />

http://www.amazon.com/exec/obidos/tg/browse/-<br />

/468496/ref=hp_hp_ct_5_2/102-2037588-3280918<br />

Antonelli, C. (1992). The economic theory of <strong>in</strong>formation networks. In C. Antonelli<br />

(Ed.), The economics of <strong>in</strong>formation networks (pp. 5-27). Amsterdam; New York:<br />

North-Holland.<br />

Arrow, K. J. (1984). The economics of <strong>in</strong>formation (Vol. 4). Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap Press<br />

of Harvard University Press.<br />

Ba, S., Wh<strong>in</strong>ston, A. B., & Zhang, H. (2000). Small companies <strong>in</strong> the digital economy. In<br />

E. Brynjolfsson & B. Kah<strong>in</strong> (Eds.), Understand<strong>in</strong>g the digital economy: data, tools, and<br />

research (pp. 185-200). Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.<br />

95


Bailey, J. P., & Bakos, Y. (1997). An exploratory study of the emerg<strong>in</strong>g role of electronic<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries [Electronic Version]. International Journal of Electronic Commerce, Vol.<br />

1 (No. 3), 7-20.<br />

Bakos, Y. J. (1991). A strategic analysis of electronic marketplaces. MIS Quarterly, Vol. 15<br />

(No. 3, Special Issue: [Strategic Use of <strong>Information</strong> Systems]), 295-310.<br />

Barnes, S., & Hunt, B. (2001). Recogniz<strong>in</strong>g the potential of e-bus<strong>in</strong>ess. In S. Barnes & B.<br />

Hunt (Eds.), E-commerce and v-bus<strong>in</strong>ess: Bus<strong>in</strong>ess models for global success (pp. 1-4.).<br />

Oxford; Boston: Butterworth-He<strong>in</strong>emann.<br />

Beal, B. D. (2002). AllAdvantage.com: An Internet <strong>in</strong>fomediary. Baton Rouge, LA: Louisiana<br />

State University, E.J. Ourso College of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess, William W. and Cather<strong>in</strong>e M.<br />

Rucks Department of Management.<br />

Beniger, J. R. (1986). The control revolution: Technological and economic orig<strong>in</strong>s of the <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

society. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.<br />

Blumenthal, M. S., & Clark, D. D. (2001). Reth<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g the design of the Internet: the end-<br />

to-end arguments vs. the brave new world. In B. Compa<strong>in</strong>e & S. Greenste<strong>in</strong><br />

(Eds.), <strong>Communication</strong>s policy <strong>in</strong> transition: The Internet and beyond (pp. 91-139).<br />

Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.<br />

Bodorik, P., & Jutla, D. (2003). Architecture for user-controlled e-privacy. Paper presented at the<br />

Proceed<strong>in</strong>g of the 2003 ACM Symposium on Applied Comput<strong>in</strong>g, Melbourne,<br />

Florida.<br />

96


Boisot, M. (1998). Knowledge assets: Secur<strong>in</strong>g competitive advantage <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formation economy.<br />

New York: Oxford University Press.<br />

Braudel, F. (1982a). The perspective of the world (1st U.S. ed. Vol. III). New York: Harper &<br />

Row.<br />

Braudel, F. (1982b). The wheels of commerce (1st U.S. ed. Vol. II). New York: Harper &<br />

Row.<br />

Bunnell, D., & Luecke, R. A. (2000). The e-Bay phenomenon: Bus<strong>in</strong>ess secrets beh<strong>in</strong>d the world's<br />

hottest Internet company. New York: Wiley.<br />

Campbell, J. E., & Carlson, M. (2002). Panopticon.com: Onl<strong>in</strong>e surveillance and the<br />

commodification of privacy. Journal of Broadcast<strong>in</strong>g and Electronic Media, Vol. 46 (No.<br />

4), 586-606.<br />

Campbell, T. S., & Kracaw, W. A. (1980). <strong>Information</strong> production, market signal<strong>in</strong>g, and<br />

the theory of f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation. The Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance, Vol. 35 (No. 4), 863-<br />

882.<br />

Cavoukian, A. (2002). The privacy payoff: How successful bus<strong>in</strong>esses build customer trust. Toronto,<br />

ON: McGraw-Hill Ryerson.<br />

Cavoukian, A., & Tapscott, D. (1997). Who knows: Safeguard<strong>in</strong>g your privacy <strong>in</strong> a networked<br />

world. New York: McGraw-Hill.<br />

Chen, Y., Ganesh, I., & Padmanabhan, V. (Fall 2002). Referral <strong>in</strong>fomediaries. Market<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Science, Vol. 21 (No. 4), 412-434.<br />

97


Chircu, A. N., & Kauffman, R. J. (1998). Strategies for Internet middlemen <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>termediation-<br />

dis<strong>in</strong>termediation-re<strong>in</strong>termediation cycle. University of M<strong>in</strong>nesota, USA.<br />

Chircu, A. N., & Kauffman, R. J. (2001). Digital <strong>in</strong>termediation <strong>in</strong> electronic commerce--<br />

the eBay model. In S. Barnes & B. Hunt (Eds.), E-commerce and v-bus<strong>in</strong>ess: Bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

models for global success (pp. 45-66). Oxford; Boston: Butterworth-He<strong>in</strong>emann.<br />

Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4 (16), 386-405.<br />

Cosimano, T. F. (1996). Intermediation. Economica, New Series, Vol. 63 (No. 249), 131-<br />

143.<br />

Culnan, M. J. (1993). "How did they get my name?": An exploratory <strong>in</strong>vestigation of<br />

consumer attitudes toward secondary <strong>in</strong>formation use. MIS Quarterly, Vol. 17 (No.<br />

3), 341-363.<br />

Delevett, P. (2002, February 19). Can you dig it? new technology mag to debut. Mercury<br />

News.com. Retrieved March 31, 2004, from<br />

http://www.mercurynews.com/mld/mercurynews/bus<strong>in</strong>ess/2701186.htm<br />

Dix, A. (no date). Infomediaries and negotiated privacy techniques. Retrieved October 17, 2003,<br />

from http://www.cfp2000.org/papers/dix.pdf<br />

Downes, L., & Mui, C. (1998). Unleash<strong>in</strong>g the killer app: Digital strategies for market dom<strong>in</strong>ance.<br />

Boston, Mass.: Harvard Bus<strong>in</strong>ess School Press.<br />

98


Dutta, S., & Segev, A. (2001). Bus<strong>in</strong>ess transformation on the Internet. In S. Barnes & B.<br />

Hunt (Eds.), E-commerce and v-bus<strong>in</strong>ess: Bus<strong>in</strong>ess models for global success (pp. 5-22).<br />

Oxford; Boston: Butterworth-He<strong>in</strong>emann.<br />

eBay. (2004). eBay privacy policy. Retrieved March 29, 2004, from<br />

http://pages.ebay.com/help/policies/privacy-policy.html<br />

E-Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Strategies. (2001, October). Amazon.NET: Creat<strong>in</strong>g an e-services platform.<br />

E-Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Strategies, Inc. Retrieved March 29, 2004, from<br />

http://www.ebstrategy.com/case_studies/AmazonNET.pdf<br />

Evans, P., & Wurster, T. S. (2000). Blown to bits: How the new economics of <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

transforms strategy. Boston, Mass.: Harvard Bus<strong>in</strong>ess School Press.<br />

Federal Trade Commission. (August 8, 2002). Microsoft settles FTC charges alleg<strong>in</strong>g false security<br />

and privacy promises. Retrieved March 27, 2004, from<br />

http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2002/08/microsoft.htm<br />

Frost, R. L. (Dec. 1980). Freedom of <strong>in</strong>formation vs. the privacy issue. Management World,<br />

Vol. 9 (Is. 12), 39.<br />

Gandy, O. H. (1993). The panoptic sort: A political economy of personal <strong>in</strong>formation. Boulder,<br />

Colo.: Westview.<br />

Garcia, D. L. (2001). Govern<strong>in</strong>g electronic commerce <strong>in</strong> a global environment. East-West<br />

center work<strong>in</strong>g papers, economic series (No. 3).<br />

99


Garcia, D. L. (2002). The architecture of global network<strong>in</strong>g technologies. In S. Sassen<br />

(Ed.), Global networks, l<strong>in</strong>ked cities (pp. 39-70). New York: Routledge.<br />

Ghosen, J. (2002). Study shows perceived risk of onl<strong>in</strong>e credit purchases l<strong>in</strong>ked to trust,<br />

familiarity with <strong>in</strong>termediaries. University at Buffalo, The State University of New York,<br />

(November 6). Retrieved February 19, 2004, from<br />

http://www.buffalo.edu/news/fast-execute.cgi/article-<br />

page.html?article=59430009<br />

Grover, V., & Teng, J. T. C. (2001). E-commerce and the <strong>in</strong>formation market.<br />

<strong>Communication</strong>s of the ACM, Vol. 44 (No. 4), 79-86.<br />

Gunnar, E., Folster, S., L<strong>in</strong>dberg, T., Pousette, T., & Taymaz, E. (1990). The knowledge<br />

based <strong>in</strong>formation economy. Stockholm: The Industrial Institute for Economic and<br />

Social Research.<br />

Hafner, K. (March 20, 2004). With Internet fraud up sharply, eBay attracts vigilantes. The<br />

New York Times. Retrieved March 20, 2004, from<br />

http://www.nytimes.com/2004/03/20/technology/20EBAY.html<br />

Hagel, J., & S<strong>in</strong>ger, M. (1999). Net worth: Shap<strong>in</strong>g markets when customers make the rules.<br />

Boston: Harvard Bus<strong>in</strong>ess School Press.<br />

Harris, S., & Hansen, A. (no date). The Internet: Chang<strong>in</strong>g the way we communicate.<br />

America's Investment <strong>in</strong> the Future. National Science Foundation. Retrieved March<br />

100


26, 2004, from<br />

http://www.nsf.gov/od/lpa/news/publicat/nsf0050/pdf/<strong>in</strong>ternet.pdf<br />

Hirshleifer, J. (1973). Where are we <strong>in</strong> the theory of <strong>in</strong>formation? The American Economic<br />

Review, Vol. 63 (No. 2, Papers and Proceed<strong>in</strong>gs of the Eighty-Fifth Annual<br />

Meet<strong>in</strong>g of the American Economic Association), 31-39.<br />

Jones, F. M. (1937). Middlemen <strong>in</strong> the domestic trade of the United States, 1800-1860. Urbana,<br />

Ill: The University of Ill<strong>in</strong>ois.<br />

Jones, G. R., & Butler, J. E. (1988). Costs, revenue and bus<strong>in</strong>ess-level strategy. The<br />

Academy of Management Review, Vol. 13 (No. 2), 202-213.<br />

Jonscher, C. (1999). The evolution of wired life: From the alphabet to the soul-catcher chip--how<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation technologies change our world. New York: Wiley.<br />

Kannan, P. K., Chang, A.-M., & Wh<strong>in</strong>ston, A. B. (2001). E-bus<strong>in</strong>ess and the <strong>in</strong>termediary<br />

role of virtual communities. In S. Barnes & B. Hunt (Eds.), E-commerce and v-<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess: Bus<strong>in</strong>ess models for global success (pp. 67-82). Oxford; Boston: Butterworth-<br />

He<strong>in</strong>emann.<br />

Karake-Shalhoub, Z. (2002). Trust and loyalty <strong>in</strong> electronic commerce: An agency theory perspective.<br />

Westport, CT: Quorum Books.<br />

Kaufman, J. H., & Powers, C. (2002). The social contract core. Paper presented at the WWW<br />

2002, Honolulu, Hawaii, USA.<br />

101


Kelly, K. (1998). New rules for the new economy: 10 radical strategies for a connected world. New<br />

York: Vik<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

K<strong>in</strong>gma, B. R. (2001). The economics of <strong>in</strong>formation: A guide to economic and cost-benefit analysis for<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation professionals (2nd ed.). Englewood, CO: Libraries Unlimited.<br />

Kotha, S. (1995). Mass customization: Implement<strong>in</strong>g the emerg<strong>in</strong>g paradigm for<br />

competitive advantage. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 16 (Special issue:<br />

Technological Transformation and the New Competitive Landscape), 21-42.<br />

Krebs, B. (January 23, 2004). 'Feedback' forgers suspended by eBay. Wash<strong>in</strong>gtonpost.com.<br />

Retrieved March 15, 2004, from http://www.wash<strong>in</strong>gtonpost.com/ac2/wp-<br />

dyn?pagename=article&node=&contentId=A42780-2004Jan23&notFound=true<br />

Lamoreaux, N. R., & Sokoloff, K. L. (2003). <strong>Intermediaries</strong> <strong>in</strong> the U.S. market for<br />

technology, 1870-1920. In S. L. Engerman & L. E. Davis (Eds.), F<strong>in</strong>ance,<br />

<strong>Intermediaries</strong>, and Economic Development (pp. 209-246). Cambridge, UK; New York:<br />

Cambridge University Press.<br />

Larson, E. (1992). The naked consumer: How our private lives become public commodities (1st ed.).<br />

New York: H. Holt.<br />

Leickly, B. L. (2003). Personal privacy, consumer <strong>in</strong>formation collection and American bus<strong>in</strong>esses:<br />

Data analysis. Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC: Georgetown University.<br />

102


Lester, T. (March 2001). The re<strong>in</strong>vention of privacy. The Atlantic Monthly, Vol. 287 (No.<br />

3). Retrieved March 15, 2004, from<br />

http://www.theatlantic.com/issues/2001/03/lester-p1.htm<br />

Lev<strong>in</strong>, A. (1999). The network is the <strong>in</strong>fomediary. Retrieved March 20, 2004, from<br />

http://www.alev<strong>in</strong>.com/<strong>in</strong>fomediary7.htm<br />

Loebbecke, C. (2001). Onl<strong>in</strong>e delivered content: Concept and bus<strong>in</strong>ess potential. In S.<br />

Barnes & B. Hunt (Eds.), E-commerce and v-bus<strong>in</strong>ess: Bus<strong>in</strong>ess models for global success<br />

(pp. 23-44). Oxford; Boston: Butterworth-He<strong>in</strong>emann.<br />

Luen<strong>in</strong>g, E. (1998). Microsoft to buy firefly. CNET News.com. Retrieved March 27, 2004,<br />

from http://news.com.com/2100-1001-210017.html?legacy=cnet<br />

Lumeria Inc. (2000a). What we are: An overview of Lumeria's "Sunsh<strong>in</strong>e" platform. Retrieved<br />

March 31, 2004, from http://www.lumeria.com/what1.shtml<br />

Lumeria Inc. (2000b). What we are: The power of you. Retrieved March 31, 2004, from<br />

http://www.lumeria.com/what.shtml<br />

Manjoo, F. (August 16, 2001). MS passport: straight to the FTC. Wired News. Retrieved<br />

March 27, 2004, from<br />

http://www.wired.com/news/privacy/0,1848,46095,00.html<br />

McMillan, J. (2002). Re<strong>in</strong>vent<strong>in</strong>g the bazaar: A natural history of markets (1st ed.). New York:<br />

Norton.<br />

103


McWilliams, B. (November 2, 2001). Steal<strong>in</strong>g MS passport's wallet. Wired News.<br />

Retrieved March 27, 2004, from<br />

http://www.wired.com/news/technology/0,1282,48105,00.html<br />

Muller, M. (2000). Infomediaries and negotiated privacy. Retrieved October 17, 2004, from<br />

http://www.cfp2000.org/news/student_reports/<strong>in</strong>fomed-muller.html<br />

National Research Council (U.S.) NII 2000 Steer<strong>in</strong>g Committee. (1996). Technology<br />

options and capabilities: what does what, how. In The unpredictable certa<strong>in</strong>ty:<br />

<strong>Information</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure through 2000 (pp. 115-160). Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.: National<br />

Academy Press.<br />

Neuman, W. R., McKnight, L. W., & Solomon, R. J. (1997). The Gordian knot: Political<br />

gridlock on the <strong>in</strong>formation highway. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.<br />

Oakes, C. (1999, August 12a). Firefly's dim light snuffed out. Wired News. Retrieved<br />

March 31, 2004, from<br />

http://www.wired.com/news/culture/0,1284,21243,00.html<br />

Oakes, C. (1999, August 12b). Privaseek seeks attention. Wired News. Retrieved October<br />

17, 2003, from http://www.wired.com/news/bus<strong>in</strong>ess/0,1367,21221,00.html<br />

Palmer, J. W., Bailey, J. P., & Faraj, S. (2000). The role of <strong>in</strong>termediaries <strong>in</strong> the<br />

development of trust on the WWW: the use and prom<strong>in</strong>ence of trusted third<br />

parties and privacy statements. Journal of Computer-Mediated <strong>Communication</strong>, Vol. 5,<br />

104


March (Is. 3). Retrieved February 18, 2004, from<br />

http://www.ascusc.org/jcmc/vol5/issue3/palmer.html<br />

Phlips, L. (1988). The economics of imperfect <strong>in</strong>formation. Cambridge [Cambridgeshire]; New<br />

York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Pomeroy, B. (n.d.). There's still cream <strong>in</strong> the middle: <strong>in</strong>fomediaries f<strong>in</strong>d a niche on the<br />

net. Retrieved October 17, 2003, from<br />

http://www.hightechcareers.com/doc999/network<strong>in</strong>g999.html<br />

Reyerson, K. (2002). The art of the deal: <strong>Intermediaries</strong> of trade <strong>in</strong> medieval Montpellier. Leiden,<br />

Netherlands; Boston: Brill.<br />

The rise of the <strong>in</strong>fomediary. (1999, June 24). The Economist. Retrieved October 17, 2003,<br />

from http://www.economist.com/Pr<strong>in</strong>terFriendly.cfm?Story_ID=215703<br />

Rose, F. (1999). The economics, concept, and design of <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>termediaries: A theoretic<br />

approach. New York: Physica-Verlag.<br />

Rosenblatt, B. (July 1999). Infomediaries help consumers rule onl<strong>in</strong>e. SunWorld.<br />

Retrieved October 17, 2003, from http://sunsite.uakom.sk/sunworldonl<strong>in</strong>e.swol-<br />

07-1999/swol-07-bookshelf.html<br />

Sampler, J. L. (1998). Redef<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry structure for the <strong>in</strong>formation age. Strategic<br />

Management Journal, Vol. 19 (No. 4, Special Issue: Editor's Choice), 343-355.<br />

Sarkar, M. B., Butler, B., & Ste<strong>in</strong>field, C. (1995). <strong>Intermediaries</strong> and cybermediaries: A<br />

cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g role for mediat<strong>in</strong>g players <strong>in</strong> the electronic marketplace. Journal of<br />

105


Computer-Mediated <strong>Communication</strong>, Vol. 1, December (No. 3). Retrieved February 18,<br />

2004, from http://www.ascusc.org/jcmc/vol1/issue3/sarkar.html<br />

Scott, J. (2000). Emerg<strong>in</strong>g patterns from the dynamic capabilities of Internet<br />

<strong>in</strong>termediaries. Journal of Computer-Mediated <strong>Communication</strong>, Vol. 5, March (Is. 3).<br />

Retrieved February 18, 2004, from<br />

http://www.ascusc.org/jcmc/vol5/issue3/scott.html<br />

Shapiro, A. L. (1999). The control revolution: How the Internet is putt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>in</strong> charge and<br />

chang<strong>in</strong>g the world we know (1st ed.). New York: PublicAffairs.<br />

Shapiro, C., & Varian, H. R. (1998). <strong>Information</strong> rules: A strategic guide to the network economy.<br />

Boston, Mass.: Harvard Bus<strong>in</strong>ess School Press.<br />

Shaw, A. W. (1912). Some problems <strong>in</strong> market distribution. The Quarterly Journal of<br />

Economics, Vol. 26 (No. 4), 703-765.<br />

Shear<strong>in</strong>, S., & Maes, P. (no date). Representation and ownership of electronic profiles.<br />

MIT Media Lab. Retrieved March 15, 2004, from<br />

http://web.media.mit.edu/~sibyl/projects/eprofile/cpf.pdf<br />

Smith, M. D., Bailey, J., & Brynjolfsson, E. (2000). Understand<strong>in</strong>g digital markets: Review<br />

and assessment. In E. Brynjolfsson & B. Kah<strong>in</strong> (Eds.), Understand<strong>in</strong>g the digital<br />

economy: Data, tools and research (pp. 99-136). Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.<br />

106


Smith, W. D. (1984). The function of commercial centers <strong>in</strong> the modernization of<br />

European capitalism: Amsterdam as an <strong>in</strong>formation exchange <strong>in</strong> the seventeenth<br />

century. The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 44 (No. 4), 985-1005.<br />

Spulber, D. F. (1996). Market microstructure and <strong>in</strong>termediation. The Journal of Economic<br />

Perspectives, Vol. 10 (No. 3), 135-152.<br />

Spulber, D. F. (1998). Market microstructure: <strong>Intermediaries</strong> and the theory of the firm.<br />

Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Sr<strong>in</strong>agesh, P., & Gong, J. (1996). Network competition and <strong>in</strong>dustry structure. NII Initiative,<br />

Bell <strong>Communication</strong>s Research Inc.<br />

Stand<strong>in</strong>g, C., & Vasudavan, T. (2001). Industry transformation <strong>in</strong> e-commerce: Web<br />

diffusion <strong>in</strong> travel agencies. In S. Barnes & B. Hunt (Eds.), E-commerce and v-<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess: Bus<strong>in</strong>ess models for global success (pp. 121-137). Oxford; Boston: Butterworth-<br />

He<strong>in</strong>emann.<br />

Ste<strong>in</strong>mueller, W. E. (1992). The economics of production and distribution of user-<br />

specific <strong>in</strong>formation via digital networks. In C. Antonelli (Ed.), The economics of<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation networks (pp. 173-194). Amsterdam; New York: North-Holland.<br />

Stigler, G. J. (1971). The economics of <strong>in</strong>formation. In D. M. Lamberton (Ed.), Economics<br />

of <strong>in</strong>formation and knowledge (pp. 61-82). Harmondsworth, Eng: Pengu<strong>in</strong> Books.<br />

107


Stiglitz, J. (1989). Markets, market failure and development. The American Economic Review,<br />

Vol. 79 (No. 2, Papers and Proceed<strong>in</strong>gs of the Hundred and First Annual Meet<strong>in</strong>g<br />

of the American Economic Association), 197-203.<br />

Swire, P. P. (2002). Why e-commerce is like a bottle of tylenol. Retrieved March 20, 2004, from<br />

http://www.peterswire.net/tylenol.doc<br />

Vora, P. (December 1999). Book review. [Review of the book Net worth: Shap<strong>in</strong>g markets when<br />

customers make the rules] Internetwork<strong>in</strong>g: Internet Technical Group. Retrieved<br />

March 20, 2004, from<br />

http://www.<strong>in</strong>ternettg.org/newsletter/dec99/review_net_worth.html<br />

Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic <strong>in</strong>stitutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational<br />

contract<strong>in</strong>g. New York: Free Press.<br />

Wolpert, S. A., & Wolpert, J. F. (1986). Economics of <strong>in</strong>formation. New York: Van Nostrand<br />

Re<strong>in</strong>hold.<br />

Wolters, M., & Hoogeweegen, M. (2001). Management support for the modular virtual<br />

organization: KLM distribution. In S. Barnes, & Hunt, B. (Ed.), E-commerce and v-<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess: Bus<strong>in</strong>ess models for global success (pp. 193-212). Oxford; Boston: Butterworth-<br />

He<strong>in</strong>emann.<br />

108

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!