28.03.2013 Views

Capital-Labor Substitution and Economic Efficiency Author(s): K. J. ...

Capital-Labor Substitution and Economic Efficiency Author(s): K. J. ...

Capital-Labor Substitution and Economic Efficiency Author(s): K. J. ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

CAPITAL-LABOR SUBSTITUTION AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 237<br />

Substituting from (29) for the efficiency ratio<br />

<strong>and</strong> taking logs we get a formula comparable<br />

to equation (8) from which our elasticity esti-<br />

mates were derived:<br />

log Y = (a + e - ea) log (W(3A<br />

Y'B WB<br />

Comparing (8) <strong>and</strong> (3I), we see that the re-<br />

gression coefficient b is equal to (o-+e-eo-), or<br />

b-e (32)<br />

b-e<br />

i - e<br />

Therefore it is only when efficiency does not<br />

vary with w - i.e. when e = o - that b is<br />

equal to o-. For e > o, o- must be still smaller<br />

than b, <strong>and</strong> therefore, a fortiori, less than i<br />

when b < i.<br />

To get a rough idea of the magnitude of the<br />

correction, we normalized the y's in Table 3 sO<br />

that the United States value equals one in each<br />

case <strong>and</strong> then fitted log y to log w by least<br />

squares.14 We obtain the following result from<br />

the combined sample of I4 observations:<br />

logy .323 log w -.039 R2 = .82.<br />

(.043)<br />

The separate industries vary somewhat, but the<br />

number of observations in each is too small for<br />

reliable estimates. Another source of informa-<br />

tion on e is provided by the comparisons of<br />

Japan with the United States in section IV,<br />

which cover io manufacturing industries. Here<br />

the median value of (yJ/yu) is about .35, cor-<br />

responding to a value of e of about .5.<br />

For values of b less than i, equation (32)<br />

shows that variation of efficiency with the wage<br />

rate will reduce the estimate of a-. Taking e= .3,<br />

values of b of .9, .8, <strong>and</strong> .7 yield values of .86,<br />

.7i, <strong>and</strong> .57. At the median value of b =.87<br />

observed in Table 2, the corresponding C- is .8i.<br />

2. Residual variation by country. The ex-<br />

tent of the deviation of observed values of value<br />

added per unit of labor in each country from the<br />

values predicted by the regression equations is<br />

shown in Table 4. Apart from errors of ob-<br />

servation, there are three main causes of these<br />

differences between the predicted value (9 = a<br />

+ b log p ) <strong>and</strong> the observed value (y = V/L):<br />

"This procedure is not strictly correct, since y is com-<br />

puted from an assumed value of a which is subsequently to<br />

be corrected, but it is roughly valid since y is insensitive to<br />

variations in a.<br />

(a) Variations in efficiency, which affect L<br />

only.<br />

(b) Variations in commodity prices, which<br />

affect both V <strong>and</strong> W/P. The net effect<br />

depends on the magnitude of the differ-<br />

ence (i - b).<br />

(c) Variations in the exchange rate, which<br />

affect V but not W/P.<br />

The following deviations in each factor are<br />

associated with positive <strong>and</strong> negative values of<br />

(y - ):<br />

Positive Residuals Negative Residuals<br />

<strong>Efficiency</strong> Relatively efficient Relatively inefficient<br />

Commodity price High Low<br />

Exchange rate Overvalued Undervalued<br />

TABLE 4.- RESIDUAL VARIATION IN (V/L)<br />

BY COUNTRY a<br />

Number of Industries<br />

Between<br />

Average Averageb Above +5% <strong>and</strong> Below<br />

V (%) +5% -5% - 5s%io<br />

() (2) (3) (4) (5)<br />

United States 384I +5 I0 II 3<br />

Canada 3226 +5 9 II 3<br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> i980 +4 7 7 8<br />

Australia I926 -I2 I 3 20<br />

Denmark I455 -8 2 6 i6<br />

Norway I393 -9 2 6 I5<br />

Puerto Rico II82 +22 9 I 8<br />

United Kingdom I059 -II I 4 I9<br />

Colombia 924 +I4 i6 2 6<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> 900 -i8 0 2 I2<br />

Mexico 524 +3 2 I9 3 X<br />

Argentina 5I9 +I0 I2 5 7<br />

Japan 476 +7 9 5 9<br />

Salvador 445 + I2 Io I 5<br />

Brazil 436 +33 9 0 1<br />

Southern Rhodesia 384 -i8 0 2 4<br />

Ceylon 26I +7 5 a 6<br />

India 24I -23 0 2 i6<br />

Iraq 2I3 +I I 0 I<br />

a Residual Ay = y derived from Table 2.<br />

b Arithmetic mean of (Ay/y).<br />

Although we cannot separate these causes in<br />

countries for which we do not have observations<br />

of relative prices, the observed residuals help in<br />

the interpretation of our previous results. Of<br />

the five countries analyzed in Table 3, the<br />

United States, Canada, <strong>and</strong> Japan have small<br />

average deviations, <strong>and</strong> hence little country bias<br />

is introduced into any conclusions based on<br />

them. The United Kingdom <strong>and</strong> India have<br />

predominantly negative residuals in V/L, prob-<br />

ably due to undervalued exchange rates. Cor-<br />

rection of Table 3-B to allow for these possible

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!