02.02.2013 Views

Phan Coxhead Vietnam Wage Paper April 14 2011 - Agricultural ...

Phan Coxhead Vietnam Wage Paper April 14 2011 - Agricultural ...

Phan Coxhead Vietnam Wage Paper April 14 2011 - Agricultural ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

1<br />

For presentation at the 8 th Midwest International Economic Development Conference, University of<br />

Wisconsin-­‐Madison, <strong>April</strong> 15-­‐16 <strong>2011</strong>.<br />

Draft only: comments welcome<br />

What happened to wages and wage premia in <strong>Vietnam</strong> during doi<br />

moi, and why?<br />

Diep <strong>Phan</strong> 1 and Ian <strong>Coxhead</strong> 2<br />

This version: <strong>April</strong> <strong>14</strong>, <strong>2011</strong><br />

Abstract<br />

We ask what has happened to wages, intersectoral wage premia, and skill premia during <strong>Vietnam</strong>’s<br />

transition from command to mixed economy. During the 1990s and 2000s, wages rose in real terms and<br />

the skill premium also increased. We find, however, that neither trend has been linear, or even<br />

monotonic, over the entire transition period. In particular, while average real wages increased between<br />

1993 and 2008, most of this increase happened during the 1990s. Skill premia likewise rose during the<br />

1990s but leveled off in the 2000s.<br />

In a small transition economy like <strong>Vietnam</strong>, wage changes have been subject to significant policy<br />

influences from trade liberalization and the momentum of domestic policy reforms—notably those<br />

targeting labor market regulations. We designate trade policy and domestic market reforms as<br />

‘treatments’ imposed on an economy where, for historical and institutional reasons, state sector and<br />

private sector labor markets are substantively segmented. With this approach we are able, using a<br />

triple-­‐difference estimator, to identify the contributions of each type of policy change to changes in<br />

wages, and to changes in intersectoral wage premia, in different phases of the economic reform<br />

process.<br />

1 Department of Economics, Beloit College, Beloit, WI, USA.<br />

2 Department of <strong>Agricultural</strong> & Applied Economics, University of Wisconsin-Madison, Madison, WI, USA.


1. Introduction<br />

2<br />

In the newly industrializing Asian economies in the 1960s and 1970s, poor and low-­‐skilled workers were<br />

the disproportionate beneficiaries of opening international trade. This is an outcome predicted by the<br />

Stolper-­‐Samuelson theorem, based as it is on the Heckscher-­‐Ohlin model of endowment-­‐based<br />

comparative advantage. Yet the experience of more recent liberalizers has frequently contradicted this<br />

hypothesis. In Latin America, skill premia and wage inequality have increased along with integration into<br />

the global market (Wood 1997; Arbache et al. 2004). Transition economies such as Poland, Hungary<br />

have also had seen similar rises in wage inequality, as has China (Knight and Song 2003). These trends<br />

may still be consistent with Heckscher-­‐Ohlin, in that the entry of China and India to the global economy<br />

over the past two decades has seen a sharp rise in the global unskilled labor endowment. Other<br />

analyses have identified Ricardian technology-­‐based comparative advantage as playing a leading role,<br />

especially in economies where industrial policy has been actively deployed to assist industries in their<br />

progress up the quality ladder (Feenstra and Hanson 1997; Zhu and Trefler 2005; Hausman, Huang and<br />

Rodrik 2007).<br />

In this paper we ask what has happened to wages, intersectoral wage premia, and skill premia during<br />

<strong>Vietnam</strong>’s period of economic reform and globalization. The <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese economy grew rapidly during<br />

the 1990s and 2000s. <strong>Wage</strong>s rose in real terms, and the skill premium also increased. Positive as these<br />

trends are, however, we find that neither has been especially linear – or even monotonic – over the<br />

entire transition period. In particular, while average real wages increased between 1993 and 2008, most<br />

of this increase happened during the 1990s; in the 2000s there was a clear slowdown in wage growth.<br />

Also, overall wage inequality and skill premia rose during the 1990s but leveled off in the 2000s.<br />

We explore these issues in this paper, beginning with a characterization of the data, and then moving<br />

into a more analytical examination of possible reasons for observed trends and puzzles. During the past<br />

two decades, the process of opening to global trade and investment coincided with a far-­‐reaching set of<br />

domestic reforms to economic policy and institutions. Both set of reforms are expected to have strong<br />

general equilibrium effects on employment and wages in <strong>Vietnam</strong>. We explore the effects of these<br />

reforms in wage data from national household living standards surveys, and consider their implications<br />

for longer-­‐term growth and development.<br />

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we examine and summarize the data,<br />

and conduct some preliminary statistical analysis. The results raise additional questions, notably about<br />

differences in returns to labor between public and private sectors, and the influence of international<br />

integration (i.e., trade and FDI). In section 3 we distill these findings in the form of a simple model of<br />

wage and skill premium determination. In section 4 we characterize these reforms as “treatments” and<br />

measure their effects on wages in state and private sector employment, and in industries more and less<br />

exposed to trade. We test some hypotheses suggested by the model and our earlier survey of data: that<br />

domestic institutions, labor market reform, and globalization are major contributors to changes in<br />

<strong>Vietnam</strong>’s wage inequality and skill premium in the 1990s and 2000s. Section 5 draws some<br />

conclusions, compares and contrasts findings from other studies, and identifies issues to be pursued in<br />

more depth in the future.


2. <strong>Vietnam</strong>’s wage growth and wage inequality 1993-­‐2008<br />

3<br />

2.1. Prior studies<br />

The literature on wage growth, wage inequality, and returns to education in <strong>Vietnam</strong> is increasingly rich<br />

(Oostendorp and Doan 2010, Doan and Gibson 2010, Imbert 2010, Sakellariou and Fang 2010, Pham and<br />

Barry 2007a and 2007b, Liu 2005 and 2006, Nguyen et al 2006, Gallup 2002, and Moock et al 1998).<br />

Most of these papers estimate variations of the Mincerian earnings equation: Gallup (2002) and Liu<br />

(2005) employ simple OLS, Doan and Gibson (2010) the Heckman method, Liu (2006) Hay’s two-­‐stage<br />

method (a generalization of Heckman’s approach), Pham and Barry 2007a and 2007b mean and quantile<br />

regression approaches, and Nguyen et al (2006) and Oostendorp and Doan (2010) difference in<br />

differences estimators. Some papers also apply various decomposition methods to explore<br />

characteristics that explain wage gaps, and study factors contributing to changes in wage gaps. For<br />

example, Sakellariou and Fang (2010) carry out an Oaxaca-­‐Blinder decomposition based on<br />

unconditional quantile regression rather than on mean regression.<br />

Perhaps because of differences in methodology, point estimates of the rate of returns to education tend<br />

to vary considerably in these papers. However, they do agree on the following trends on wage growth<br />

and changes in returns to education. First, wage levels increased rapidly in <strong>Vietnam</strong> since doi moi.<br />

Sakellariou and Fang (2010) document that real earnings doubled for men and more than doubled for<br />

women from 1998 to 2008. Second, returns to education are low in <strong>Vietnam</strong>, but have increased over<br />

time. Doan and Gibson (2010), using OLS and Heckman estimators, find that the rate of return to one<br />

additional year of schooling rose from about 3% in 1993 to about 10% in 2008.<br />

Third, there is strong evidence of wage differential and labor market segmentation in various<br />

dimensions: gender, ethnicity, regional, and institution (public/state vs. private sector). For example,<br />

men in <strong>Vietnam</strong> on average earn more than women, even after controlling for differences in education,<br />

experience, and other characteristics. But this gap has been reducing over time. Pham and Barry<br />

(2007b), using a quantile regression approach, find that this earning gap was 31% in 1993 but<br />

diminished significantly to 19% by 1998 and exhibited stability until 2002. Liu (2006) documented that<br />

from 1993-­‐1998, the mean real wage increased by 68% for males but 84% for women. Nguyen et al<br />

(2006) find that females get paid 15% less than men on average, controlling for differences in human<br />

capital (they use VLSS 1998 and VHLSS 2002). The gender wage gap was found to narrow down with<br />

primary and secondary education but not higher levels of education. This is because female workers<br />

with lower educational levels benefited dis-­‐proportionately from labor-­‐intensive export growth, a result<br />

found in many other studies of trade liberalization impacts on <strong>Vietnam</strong> (e.g., Jenkins 2002).<br />

2.2. Data and descriptive statistics<br />

The primary data source for this paper is the <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese Living Standard Surveys: VLSS 1993 and 1998,<br />

and VHLSS 2002, 2004, 2006, and 2008. 3 The first lines in Tables 1 and 2 show that wages have been<br />

consistently rising over the years and for all groups. The trend for overall wage inequality, measured by<br />

3 Please refer to Appendix A for data notes.


4<br />

the Gini coefficient of average hourly wages, has been uneven. The coefficient rose from 0.38 in 1993 to<br />

0.42 in 2002, but declined to 0.36 in 2004 and 0.35 in 2006, then finally increased again to 0.39.<br />

While there was wage growth for all groups, its pace has been unequal across groups, and the trend has<br />

not been linear. From 1993 through 2008, the change in log average real hourly wages was 0.66 for<br />

women and only 0.57 for men (see Table 2). As a result, there has been a decline in the gender wage<br />

gap. Most of this decline happened from 1993 through 2002. Since 2002, the gender wage gap has<br />

stayed relatively stable.<br />

The rural-­‐urban wage gap rose significantly in the 1990s, peaked in 2002, dropped in 2004 and 2006, but<br />

climbed up again in 2008. This trend might be due to rising urban living costs and the speed with which<br />

nominal wages kept up with this rise. In the period 2006-­‐2008, inflation rates were high in <strong>Vietnam</strong>,<br />

largely due to higher energy and food prices. 4 These, coupled with rising real estate prices must have<br />

pushed up urban living costs relative to rural living costs. Indeed, the urban price deflators for the years<br />

2006 and 2008 were 1.23 and 1.18, respectively. These are very high compared to years 2002 and 2004,<br />

when the urban price deflators were only about 1.07 and 1.06, respectively. Nominal wages might not<br />

have increased fast enough to keep up with the unexpected and sharp increase in urban living costs in<br />

2006, so real wage growth in 2006 for urban workers might have been lowered.<br />

In 1993, ratio of the average wage of the Kinh ethnic majority to the average wage of ethnic minorities<br />

was quite low at 1.08. But there was a sharp increase in this ratio from 1993-­‐2002 (1.84 at its peak in<br />

2002). After that, it decreased to 1.34 in 2004 and became stable at this level until 2008.<br />

Another interesting revelation from Table 1 is the wage differential between public and private sectors.<br />

In 1993, public sector workers’ average wage was lower than that of private sector workers. But by<br />

2002, public sector workers’ average wage was 170% that of private sector workers, as wage grew much<br />

faster in the public sector (wage growth rates were 27.6% in 1993-­‐1998 and 23.02% in 1998-­‐2002 for<br />

public sector, while the rates were 15.91% and 6.15% for private sector; see Table 2). In the period<br />

2002-­‐2008 however, wage growth rate in the private sector started to catch up with that of public<br />

sector. Consequently, public to private wage ratio declined from 1.7 in 2002 to 1.57 in 2004, then<br />

remained stable until 2008.<br />

Finally, wage growth has been higher for those with higher levels of education (see Table 2), leading to a<br />

rise in skill premia. As can be seen in Figure 1, in 1993 there was hardly any skill premium, measured by<br />

the ratio of the average wage of those with a particular educational degree to those without any degree.<br />

This must have been a result of central planning, in which wages were institutionally set rather than<br />

determined by market forces. From 1993 through 2002, as the economy went through a series of<br />

domestic reforms, there was a dramatic increase in skill premium, especially for college-­‐educated<br />

workers. It’s quite interesting however that from 2002-­‐2008, this rise in skill premium has leveled off.<br />

4 Large capital inflows also made a significant contribution to rising inflation.


5<br />

Our descriptive analysis so far suggests that the labor market in <strong>Vietnam</strong> behaved very differently in the<br />

1990s and in the 2000s. There might exist one or more structural breaks in the trend of wage growth<br />

and wage inequality in different dimensions between the two periods.<br />

2.3. Determinants of wages<br />

While the descriptive analysis yielded many interesting results, it has not controlled for covariates when<br />

examining factors associated with wage differentials. We thus ran basic Mincerian wage regressions<br />

using OLS. 5 The findings mostly confirm those in the descriptive analysis (see Tables 3a and 3b). Over<br />

the years, there were consistent increases in returns to education, especially to college education. Table<br />

3a shows that, in 1993, there was no return to education, as the coefficient on years of schooling was<br />

about zero, after controlling for experience, gender, and other characteristics. In 1998, this coefficient<br />

jumped to 0.032, meaning that one additional year of schooling increases the log wage by 3.2%.<br />

Thereafter, the coefficient gradually increased and by 2008, it reached 0.051. Even after these increases,<br />

by 2008, returns to education in <strong>Vietnam</strong> are still very low by international standards (e.g. Cai, Park and<br />

Zhou 2008). This raises concerns regarding the incentive to invest in human capital.<br />

Table 3b replaced years of schooling with dummies for different educational levels. In 1993, there were<br />

hardly any differences in wages among those with varying educational levels. Only college graduates had<br />

some positive returns to their education. Even then, the return was very small: a college degree would<br />

increase the log wage by only 17% relative to those without any education. Returns to different levels of<br />

education increased steadily over the years from 1993 through 2008. Returns to college degree<br />

increased the most, as already discussed in Table 3a and in the descriptive analysis.<br />

Results for other dimensions of wage differentials also mirror those in the descriptive analysis. It seems<br />

clear that there is a structural change in <strong>Vietnam</strong>’s labor market from the 1990s to the 2000s, and the<br />

year 2002 seems to be the turning point. In particular, there is a leveling off or slowdown of wage<br />

growth and wage differentials after 2002. Public sector premium increased in the 1990s but decreased<br />

in the 2000s. Returns to experienced increased up to year 2002 then stabilized. Gender wage gap<br />

decreased in the 1990s then stabilized (but it increased again in 2008). Rural-­‐urban wage gap increased<br />

from 1993-­‐2002 then decreased afterwards.<br />

2.4. <strong>Wage</strong> changes: decomposition analysis<br />

To further understand the sources of rapid wage growth from 1993 through 2008, we carried out an<br />

Oaxaca-­‐Blinder decomposition for the three periods 1993-­‐1998, 1998-­‐2002, and 2002-­‐2008.<br />

ln !"#$ !! − ln !"#$ !! = ! !,!!<br />

!<br />

= ! !,!!<br />

!<br />

∗ ! !,!! + ! !,!!<br />

!<br />

∗ ! !,!!<br />

∗ ! !,!! − ! !,!! + ! !,!! − ! !,!!<br />

!<br />

5 We also ran Heckman regressions to control for sample selection bias. Identification variables include dependency<br />

ratio, dummy for being household head, and non-wage income (non-wage income variables are not available for<br />

survey years 1993 and 1998). The results (see Table 9) suggest that there are no major differences between OLS and<br />

Heckman estimates, even though in all regressions, the null hypothesis that rho=0 can be rejected. Hence, we decide<br />

to present only OLS results in the main paper.<br />

! !,!!


6<br />

The first term on the right hand side is the increase in log wage due to changes in characteristics<br />

between year t1 and year t2 (such as an increase in years of schooling or reallocation from rural to<br />

urban sector). The second term is the increase in log wage due to changes in returns to characteristics<br />

(such as an increase in skill premium or public sector premium). The decomposition analysis (see Table<br />

4) makes it clear that changes in returns to labor in <strong>Vietnam</strong> since 1993 are due to either increase in the<br />

base wage (i.e., wage growth for everyone) or to changes in returns to existing worker characteristics<br />

such as skills and experience, rather than to changes in those characteristics themselves. From 1993 to<br />

1998, increase in returns to education explained almost half of the wage growth. During 1998-­‐2002 and<br />

2002-­‐2008, increase in returns to education continued to be one of the most important contributors to<br />

wage growth, although no longer as much as in 1993-­‐1998 and not statistically significant. This result is<br />

consistent with figure 1, which shows the dramatic increase in returns to education from 1993 to 1998<br />

compared with the later periods. The result also motivates a deeper search for the sources of changes in<br />

returns to characteristics, especially changes in returns to education.<br />

2.5. Discussion<br />

We summarize the main findings so far here:<br />

1. <strong>Wage</strong>s have been rising rapidly.<br />

2. Overall wage inequality increased from 1993 through 2002, but started to level off from 2002 to<br />

2006, then increased somewhat again in 2008.<br />

3. Returns to education were extremely low in 1993, increased significantly through 2002, then<br />

continued to increase albeit at a slower rate from 2002 to 2008.<br />

4. Changes in observable worker characteristics account for a very small share of the total change<br />

in wages. Growth in the base wage and changes in the returns to characteristics account for<br />

most of the wage growth.<br />

5. Public sector premium has been rising, suggesting a deepening of labor market segmentation<br />

between the state sector and the private sector.<br />

Structurally, the process of growth, reform and globalization that <strong>Vietnam</strong> has undergone could have<br />

conflicting effects on wages and skill premia. Growth raises labor demand and should, other things<br />

equal, increase the demand for skills more rapidly than that for ‘raw’ labor as the expanding economy<br />

demands more specialized services in banking, finance, insurance, management and related tasks.<br />

Reforms have had a large impact on the relative position of public and private sector activity, and on the<br />

degree of engagement of foreign capital and joint-­‐venture operations in production. As discussed in<br />

more detail below, these changes could have an influence on the growth of relative demand for skills.<br />

Finally, globalization requires a reorientation of large parts of the economy to the norms of the<br />

international market. Price convergence (in activities with comparative advantage, from below; in those<br />

with comparative disadvantage, from above) helps determine changes in returns to all factors, including<br />

labor. In the case of a labor-­‐abundant, low-­‐skill economy such as <strong>Vietnam</strong>, the Stolper-­‐Samuelson<br />

theorem predicts a rise in returns to unskilled wages relative to those for skills.<br />

In addition to globalization, the influence of economic and institutional reforms is also of particular<br />

importance. <strong>Vietnam</strong>’s experience, as a transitional economy, is unusual in the East Asian setting; only


China has undergone such a sweeping change in economic organization, from quasi-­‐closed and almost<br />

entirely state-­‐controlled to mainly open, with public and private institutions coexisting. One<br />

characteristic of the old system was a clear distinction between wages, returns to skills, and other<br />

conditions of public and private sector labor markets. Table 5 highlights contrasts between these<br />

institutions in the returns to labor overall, and in the spread of wages by education. 6<br />

7<br />

Moreover, differences in returns to skills persist throughout the period covered by our data, as seen in<br />

Table 6. Returns to schooling in <strong>Vietnam</strong>’s public sector were initially low (1993) but rose very sharply.<br />

Those in the private sector have remained low throughout, with the consequence that the ratio of<br />

public/private returns to schooling rose from 1.6 in 1993 to a peak of 5.2 in 2004, before settling back to<br />

3.4 by 2008.<br />

Finally, the contribution to employment growth by institution has been dramatically different. Table 6<br />

shows changes in the structure of employment. The share of wage employment has been increasing<br />

while that of self-­‐employment has been decreasing, an expected trend for a developing economy.<br />

Within wage employment, public sector’s contribution to employment is much smaller compared to that<br />

of the private sector. This should be judged against the high GDP share of the state sector, which has<br />

been declining since the 1990s albeit at a slow rate (from 40.18% in 1995 to 35.5% in 2008 7 ). The state<br />

sector has not generated many jobs despite its large share in the economy’s GDP, although it has slowly<br />

become more labor-­‐intensive over the years. Therefore, it seems that public and private sector<br />

employers are responding to different signals, or applying different rules in deciding on how much labor<br />

to employ, and what wages to pay.<br />

In short, both the average wage and the returns to skills show strong initial differences between public<br />

and private sector workers, especially in first decade of <strong>Vietnam</strong>’s modern economic growth experience.<br />

Differences in wages and skill premia are reinforced by differential growth rates of employment.<br />

3. Theory<br />

In the foregoing section we saw that changes in observable worker characteristics account for a<br />

relatively small share of the total change in wages in <strong>Vietnam</strong>. We also found considerable, if<br />

circumstantial, evidence for a form of labor market segmentation between the state sector and the<br />

private sector. This was revealed in persistently different wages by skill, skill premia, and employment<br />

trends relative to output growth rates. These findings raise two interesting questions. To what extent<br />

do domestic institutions and reforms govern the evolution of wages and skill premia? What is the<br />

contribution of globalization—the very rapid opening to world markets that <strong>Vietnam</strong> underwent at the<br />

same time? In this section we construct a simple model with which to form hypotheses about wage and<br />

skill premium trends in the globalizing <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese economy. This sets the stage for empirical<br />

hypothesis tests in section 4.<br />

6 Interestingly, these data have a strong similarity to those from a comparable period in China, where the ratio of<br />

average state to non-state sector wages rose from 0.4 in 1988 to approximate parity (0.9) in 2001, while the<br />

coefficient of variation of wages across institutions fell from 0.46 to 0.16 (Cai, Park and Zhao 2008, Table 6.4).<br />

7 Data from GSO website.


8<br />

The workhorse of the returns-­‐to-­‐labor literature is the Mincer’s “human capital earnings function,” in<br />

which the rate of return to an individual’s schooling is estimated by reference to years of education and<br />

a polynomial in experience (Mincer 1974). Subsequent generalizations have brought in other worker<br />

characteristics such as gender and ethnicity, as well as conditioning variables such as family background,<br />

cognitive ability and school quality, generating a class of models known as “returns to schooling<br />

functions” (for a survey, see Card 2008). An ex post interpretation of this function also includes post-­‐<br />

schooling information such as industry and location (e.g., rural v. urban). Here, we adopt a general<br />

equilibrium interpretation of the returns to schooling function; in this, each worker earns a wage equal<br />

to the average rate plus or minus premia due to individual characteristics such as gender and ethnicity.<br />

The average wage itself is a function of general equilibrium variables: prices, policies, and aggregate<br />

factor endowments.<br />

Our analysis of the <strong>Vietnam</strong> case is special due to the qualitatively different treatment of private and<br />

public sector workers. On one hand, the public sector in <strong>Vietnam</strong> has always been very tightly<br />

regulated, and remains so to this day. On the other, in the first decade of economic reforms (roughly<br />

1986-­‐1998) the <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese government introduced a number of changes directly and indirectly<br />

affecting wages and conditions for public sector workers. Direct influences included a wholesale reform<br />

of the public sector, resulting in the loss of an estimated 1.5 million public sector jobs, and the 1994<br />

introduction of a new Labor Law, which relaxed somewhat the regulations governing public sector<br />

workers’ compensation and benefits (Moock et al., 2003). These labor law reforms were thought by<br />

contemporary observers to have had little direct impact on private sector workers, as “in general the<br />

private sector was not hampered by the more rigid labor remuneration regulations” to which<br />

government workers and those in state-­‐owned enterprises were subject (World Bank 1995: 63).<br />

Indirect influences included early initiatives to “equitize” (partially privatize) some state-­‐owned<br />

enterprises, and the relaxation of statutory limitations on joint venture partnerships with foreign capital.<br />

These liberalizing reforms were adopted in the 1990s while retaining very high rates of protection and<br />

other forms of preferential treatment for state-­‐owned enterprises (Athukorala 2006). As the World<br />

Bank (1995) concluded, “These privileges -­‐ in particular preferential access to land and foreign trade<br />

quotas and licenses -­‐ have played a very important role in the concentration of foreign direct investment<br />

in joint ventures with state enterprises, which is transferring to them new financial, managerial and<br />

technological resources.” Undoubtedly, the differential access of SOEs to foreign capital and joint<br />

venture partnerships in the 1990s helped raise their productivity, and along with it the returns to their<br />

labor force—subject, of course, to the restrictions on compensation imposed by the Labor Law.<br />

These empirical conclusions from contemporary observers of the <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese economy motivate a<br />

model in which the labor market – and especially that for skilled workers – is not well integrated<br />

between public and private institutions. Hiring and wages in the latter depend on conventional<br />

profitability calculations, while in the former, we find persuasive evidence of non-­‐market wage-­‐setting.<br />

This is consistent both with tighter regulation of state wages, and—and in the case of state-­‐owned<br />

enterprises, with the partial monetization in wages of rents attributable to quasi-­‐monopoly status and<br />

other statutory privileges.


9<br />

In stylized form, we can think of the private sector returns to schooling function as depending on a<br />

combination of the workers’ own characteristics and the mean wage as determined by macroeconomic<br />

supply and demand factors. Demand factors are dominated of course by the prices earned industries,<br />

whereas supply factors are dominated by long-­‐run labor force growth and participation rates, as well as<br />

any transfer of workers from public to private sector employment-­‐-­‐ itself the indirect impact of policies<br />

in government and state-­‐owned industries.<br />

Formally, we can derive the aggregate private sector wage function from an aggregate revenue (or GDP)<br />

function (Dixit and Norman 1980). Let w be the average wage, p be a vector of output prices, and V be<br />

the total factor endowment vector, and let s(π) be the demand for each factor from State employers.<br />

Then aggregate private sector output (G) is produced from the net factor endowment vector: G =G(p, v),<br />

where v = V-­‐s(κ). The factor price function is obtained by differentiation of G(p, v) with respect to the<br />

labor element of the net endowment vector, v. In general vector notation,<br />

w = ∂G(p, V-­‐s(κ))/∂v.<br />

The assumption here is that s(κ) is determined by state policies, not by market forces, and that this gives<br />

rise to a segmented factor market.<br />

This model captures the general equilibrium influences on w from all sources. It is helpful to think of it<br />

in the form of a total differential:<br />

dw = (∂w/∂p)dp + (∂w/∂v)[dV -­‐ (∂s/∂π)dκ].<br />

In a small open economy, the first product on the right hand side captures Stolper-­‐Samuelson effects<br />

associated with trade and trade policy reform. The second product captures influences on factor<br />

returns associated with changes in total factor endowments. The third product captures the effects of<br />

state policies—in <strong>Vietnam</strong> for example, the elimination of about 1.5m jobs in government and SOEs in<br />

the mid-­‐1990s, as previously discussed.<br />

Finally, the wage wi earned by any individual with a vector of characteristics xi ≠ x will deviate from the<br />

average:<br />

wi = βxi + w(p, V-­‐s(κ)),<br />

where β is a vector of returns to characteristics.<br />

With this theoretical and empirical context, it is not obvious what increased trade openness will do to<br />

wages and overall inequality in a poor developing country such as <strong>Vietnam</strong>. On the one hand, <strong>Vietnam</strong><br />

has been pursuing labor-­‐intensive export-­‐oriented growth, as evidenced by the rapid production and<br />

export growth of labor-­‐intensive industries. The Stolper-­‐Samuelson theorem would predict a decline in<br />

both the skill premium and wage inequality. On the other hand, growth due to greater openness –<br />

especially if that openness is tempered by some degree of industrial policy, as Hausmann, Huang and<br />

Rodrik (2007) assert it has been in China – could stimulate a rapid rise in the skill premium. Conversely,


changes in government policies that affect state sector employment have the potential to shift the<br />

supply of skills, which also influences the private sector returns to schooling function.<br />

10<br />

This model is preliminary in nature and has many shortcomings (it is, for example, static, and imposes a<br />

number of assumptions, among them competitive wage-­‐setting in private sector employment). Its<br />

virtue is its simplicity; it draws attention to what are arguably the dominant sources of wage<br />

determination for private sector workers: their own characteristics (e.g., education); their marginal<br />

value product in employment which is affected by reforms such as trade liberalization, and changes in<br />

aggregate supply, including those resulting from policies affecting state-­‐controlled employment.<br />

4. Sources of differential wage growth<br />

The <strong>Vietnam</strong> data show that between 1993 and 2008, wages and the skill premium rose substantially.<br />

But it is easy also to see that virtually all of the growth took place in the first decade of the reform era,<br />

and that with the sole exception of the college degree/no education ratio in year 2008, every measure<br />

of the premium declined after 2002. What is behind these contrasting trends? This is not an easy<br />

question to answer in an economy where rapid growth is causing many things to change at once.<br />

Moreover, <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese statistical sources on some variables (such as workers’ wages and employment<br />

by skills) are very difficult to reconcile with those providing other kinds of information, such as<br />

employment, output and profits at firm or industry level. Our approach in this study relies primarily on<br />

VHLSS sources. 8 This allows us to retain the richness of the individual data in VHLSS, at the cost of<br />

constraining somewhat our ability to characterize the determinants of the general equilibrium wage.<br />

Our solution is to consider the two types of policy innovations– those addressing labor and other<br />

conditions in government and state-­‐owned enterprises, and reforms affecting the profitability of<br />

production of tradables versus goods for the home market– as exogenous treatments, the effects of<br />

which we measure against trends reflecting underlying economic growth and development and<br />

captured in the evolution of wages for a control group. This section describes the methodology and<br />

reports econometric results of hypothesis tests.<br />

4.1. Empirical methodology: triple difference estimator<br />

Our goal is to measure the effects of two policy “treatments” on wage growth and wage inequality.<br />

Because we have two independent treatments, we employ a triple difference (DDD) estimator. To<br />

measure the “treatment” effects of trade liberalization and domestic reform, we divide the sample by<br />

public and nonpublic sector, and also by tradable and non-­‐tradable industries (see appendix B for a list<br />

of industries in each category). While labor market reforms could have affected workers in both the<br />

public and private sectors, the evidence presented in section 2 suggests that they had first-­‐order<br />

impacts only on the public sector. Thus, in a single-­‐treatment difference in difference (DD) analysis, we<br />

can think of public sector workers as the treatment group and private sector workers as the control:<br />

!"# !"#! ! = ! ! + ! ! ∗ !"#$2 ! + ! !!"#$%& ! + ! !!"#$2 ! ∗ !"#$%& ! + ! !! + ! !<br />

8 In related research currently in progress, we approach the same question via other sources such as Enterprise<br />

Surveys.


11<br />

where Year2 is a dummy for the later year, Public is a dummy for public sector worker, Z is a vector of<br />

workers’ characteristics including education, experience, trade dummy, and other covariates. ! !<br />

represents the time trend in the control group, i.e., the increase in wage from year 1 to year 2 for<br />

private sector workers. ! ! represents the wage differential between private and public sector workers in<br />

year 1. ! ! represents the difference in changes over time between groups, i.e., the average treatment<br />

effect. If ! ! > 0, this is evidence that labor market reform between year 1 and year 2 raised wages in<br />

the public sector more than it did in the private sector.<br />

In this analysis, there is an unavoidable spillover from the treatment group to the control group. In<br />

general equilibrium, wages offered by government and state firms would certainly affect wages offered<br />

by private employers. To the extent that this is so, estimates of the treatment effect (! ! above) suffer<br />

from a bias. If we find that ! ! = 0 , we cannot conclude that there isn’t any significant treatment effect<br />

(labor market reform did not impact the labor market, whether public or private sector workers)<br />

because the actual ! ! might be larger in the absence of the spillover. But if we find that the treatment<br />

effect is positive (labor market reform impacted public sector workers more than private sector<br />

workers), then we can conclude that there is a treatment effect, and that our estimate of the treatment<br />

effect is an underestimate of the actual effect, due to downward bias caused by the spillover.<br />

Similarly, the trade liberalization should have first-­‐order effects on tradable industries only. In this case,<br />

therefore, we can consider workers in tradable industries as the treatment group, and workers in non-­‐<br />

tradable industries as the control. Once again considering only the single-­‐treatment (DD) version:<br />

!"# !"#$ ! = ! ! + ! ! ∗ !"#$2 ! + ! !!"#$% ! + ! !!"#$2 ! ∗ !"#$% ! + ! !! + ! !<br />

! ! captures the time trend in the control group, i.e., the wage increase from year 1 to year 2 for workers<br />

in tradable industries. ! ! captures the wage premium for workers in tradable industries in year 1.<br />

Finally, ! ! captures the difference in changes over time between groups, or the treatment effect of<br />

trade liberalization. If ! ! > 0, this is evidence that wages increased more for workers in tradable<br />

industries. On the other hand, ! ! < 0 means that wages increased less for workers in tradable<br />

industries. In this DD, there is again a spillover effect similar to that in the DD analysis for public vs.<br />

private sector. So again, while a positive ! ! allows us to conclude that there is a statistically significant<br />

effect of trade liberalization, we only have an underestimate of the effect.<br />

In principle, we can estimate the above two DD models above and examine the impact of domestic<br />

reform and trade liberalization separately. But since these two reforms occurred simultaneously there<br />

is potential for wage variations in three dimensions: between time periods, between public and private<br />

sectors, and between tradable and non-­‐tradable industries. Because of initial differences among<br />

institutions, for example, the wage offered to a public sector worker in a tradable industry might vary<br />

over time in ways that differ from that offered to a private sector worker. To allow for this, we use a<br />

triple difference estimator:<br />

!"# !"#$ ! = ! ! + ! ! ∗ !"#$2 + ! ! ∗ !"#$% + ! ! ∗ !"#$%&<br />

+ ! ! ∗ !"#$2 ∗ !"#$% + ! ! ∗ !"#$% ∗ !"#$%& + ! ! ∗ !"#$%& ∗ !"#$2<br />

+ ! ∗ !"#$2 ∗ !"#$% ∗ !"#$%& + ! ∗ ! + ! !


In this expression, the triple difference effect is:<br />

12<br />

!!! = !" !" ! !" !" !"<br />

! ! − !! − !! − !!<br />

!" !"<br />

− !!"<br />

! !" !"<br />

− !!" − !!"<br />

!"<br />

− ! !"<br />

The first term in brackets is the difference in wage change between tradable and non-­‐tradable industries<br />

for public sector workers. The second bracketed term is the difference in wage change between trade<br />

and non-­‐traded industries for non-­‐public sector workers. The DDD method allows us to examine<br />

whether changes in wage from year 1 to year 2 vary by both institution (public vs. private sector) and by<br />

trade status.<br />

By differentiation, we see that the marginal impact on log wage of being in the public sector is:<br />

∂log (!"#$ !)<br />

!!"#$%& = ! ! + ! ! ∗ !"#$! + ! ! ∗ !"#$2 + ! ∗ !"#$2 ∗ !"#$%<br />

A positive ! ! means that there is a public sector premium in year 1 (the average wage in public sector is<br />

higher than that in private sector in year 1). A positive ! ! implies that public sector premium is higher<br />

for workers in tradable industries in year 1. A positive ! ! says that public sector wage has increased<br />

from year 1 to year 2. If ! > 0 and ! ! > 0, then the increase in public sector wage is larger for tradable<br />

industry workers. If ! > 0 and ! ! < 0, then the decrease in public sector wage is less for tradable<br />

industry workers. If ! < 0 and ! ! > 0, the increase in public sector wage is smaller for tradable industry<br />

workers. If ! < 0 and ! ! < 0, the decrease in public sector wage is larger for tradable industry workers.<br />

The marginal impact on log wage of being in a tradable industry is:<br />

∂log (!"#$ !)<br />

!!"#$% = ! ! + ! ! ∗ !"#$2 + ! ! ∗ !"#$%& + ! ∗ !"#$2 ∗ !"#$%&<br />

If ! ! > 0, it means that there is a trade sector premium in year 1. If ! ! > 0, average wage in tradable<br />

industries has increased from year 1 to year 2. If ! ! > 0, the tradable sector premium is higher for<br />

public sector workers in year 1. If ! > 0 and ! ! > 0, then the increase in the tradable sector wage is<br />

larger for public sector workers. If ! > 0 and ! ! < 0, then the decrease in the tradable sector wage is<br />

less for public sector workers. If ! < 0 and ! ! > 0, the increase in the tradable sector wage is smaller for<br />

public sector workers. If ! < 0 and ! ! < 0, the decrease in the tradable sector wage is larger for public<br />

sector workers.<br />

4.2. Estimation results<br />

Table 8 presents the DDD estimation results. Many coefficients have signs as expected. For example,<br />

year 2 dummy is always positive (! ! > 0), implying that there was wage growth in all groups for all<br />

periods. There was a negative public sector premium in 1993 and 1998 (! ! < 0 in the first two periods’<br />

regressions), a remnant of central planning. By 2002, the public sector had a positive wage premium<br />

(! ! > 0 in the last period’s regression). However, ! ! is positive in all periods, which indicates that the<br />

public sector premium increased in all periods. ! ! < 0 in the first two periods, so the tradable sector


premium actually decreased during 1993 through 2002. But during 2002-­‐2008, it increased (! ! < 0).<br />

These results have already been found in the basic wage regressions in Tables 3a and 3b.<br />

13<br />

! ! is positive in all periods but statistically significant only in the last period’s regression. This result has<br />

two simultaneous implications for the year 2002: public sector premium is higher for workers in tradable<br />

industries, and the tradable sector premium is higher for workers in the public sector.<br />

Finally, the coefficient of the most interest is the triple interaction term, !. It is positive in the first<br />

period 1993-­‐1998, not significant (positive and small) in 1998-­‐2002, and negative in 2002-­‐2008. In the<br />

first period 1993-­‐1998, since ! > 0 and ! ! > 0, the increase in public sector wage is larger for tradable<br />

industry workers. Also, since ! > 0 and ! ! < 0, the decrease in the tradable sector wage is less for<br />

public sector workers. The two results both imply that there is an interaction between institutions and<br />

trade: in the early years of doi moi there was an advantage in being a public sector worker in a tradable<br />

industry.<br />

During this early period of reform, even though public sector workers had lower average wage, they saw<br />

faster wage growth due to the labor market reform. This wage growth differential was even more<br />

pronounced if public sector workers also happened to be in a tradable industry. This interaction effect<br />

might be a result of incomplete liberalization. In the 1990s, although <strong>Vietnam</strong> liberalized markets and<br />

international trade and implemented policies to attract foreign direct investments, there remained a<br />

heavy bias toward joint ventures with state firms in tradable industries, mainly at the higher end of the<br />

capital-­‐intensity range (World Bank 1995). 9 Thus, workers in state firms in tradable industries must have<br />

enjoyed rapid wage growth not only thanks to labor market reform, but also thanks to the ability of<br />

these firms to attract large quantities of new investment both from the domestic economy and from<br />

abroad. For tradable industry workers not in the public sector, wages relative to workers in non-­‐tradable<br />

industries decreased from 1993 to 2002. So the net impact of trade liberalization on the overall labor<br />

market, being an aggregation of conflicting trends in public and private sectors, was limited during this<br />

period.<br />

In 2002-­‐2008, the trend reversed. Since ! < 0 and ! ! > 0, the increase in the public sector wage is<br />

smaller for tradable industry workers. Also, since ! < 0 and ! ! > 0, the increase in the tradable sector<br />

wage is smaller for public sector workers. That is, even though both public sector workers and tradable<br />

industry workers saw their premium rise during 2002-­‐2008, this rise would be less if a worker was in<br />

both the public sector and a tradable industry. So again, there is an interaction between institution and<br />

trade: in the second decade of doi moi, there was a disadvantage in being a public sector worker in a<br />

tradable industry.<br />

By the 2000s, the country deepened external sector reforms, signing a bilateral trade agreement with<br />

the USA (2001) and preparing for WTO accession (1997). Domestic reforms began to level the playing<br />

9 In its report, the World Bank noted that “the vast majority of FDI has financed joint ventures with [State-­‐owned<br />

enterprises], whose capital contribution to the joint venture has usually consisted of land use rights. Several<br />

reasons have contributed to this trend: the relatively small size of most private enterprises, their concentration on<br />

few industrial subsectors, their more limited connections with decision makers, and -­‐most important -­‐ their limited<br />

access to land” (p.35).


<strong>14</strong><br />

field between state and private industries. Passage of the Enterprise Laws in 2000 and 2005 stimulated<br />

FDI not only in the state sector but also in the private sector, and not only in capital-­‐intensive industries<br />

but also, increasingly, in labor-­‐intensive industries. All these reforms had the impact of expanding labor-­‐<br />

intensive tradable industries, which have become the engines of export and employment growth in<br />

<strong>Vietnam</strong>. This in turn raised the wages that workers in tradable industries received relative to those in<br />

non-­‐tradable industries (! ! > 0 in 2002-­‐2008). But this rise was smaller for public sector workers in<br />

tradable industries. By the 2000s, even though public sector workers continued to experience a rise in<br />

their wage premium, the rise was no longer as large (! ! = 0.135 in 1993-­‐1998 and ! ! = 0.336 in 1998-­‐<br />

2002, but it was only 0.052 in 2002-­‐2008). This deceleration in the rise of public sector premium might<br />

be because the impact of labor market reform had already run its course. Another reason is that in the<br />

2000s, state firms started to face more competition from private firms, or from joint ventures between<br />

domestic and foreign firms.<br />

In short, through the DDD analysis, we have been able to trace the impacts on wages of increased<br />

economic openness and labor market reforms, and unpack interactions between the two. There is<br />

evidence that labor market reforms had a stronger impact on the <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese labor market in the early<br />

period of doi moi, while in the later period, it was continued opening to the global economy that had a<br />

stronger impact.<br />

These findings extend and to some extent unify those of prior contributions to this literature. Imbert<br />

(2010) documented the considerable increase in average earnings of public sector workers from 1993 to<br />

2006, following labor market reform. Taking into account the effect of unobserved worker<br />

characteristics, the author found that the rise in public sector premium cannot be explained by a change<br />

in worker selection into the sector. Rather, it’s explained by differences in returns to characteristics, or<br />

sectoral differences in wage setting, indicating dualism in the labor market. Nguyen et al (2006)<br />

analyzed the impact of trade liberalization on wage structure in <strong>Vietnam</strong>, in particular the rate of returns<br />

to education and gender wage gap, but found only limited evidence of an impact. Oostendorp and Doan<br />

(2010) on the other hand, found that trade liberalization reduces the return to education by 1.2-­‐3.6%.<br />

Most of this decline was due to changes in the industry distribution of employment, not due to the<br />

decline in Mincerian return. Our analysis has shown the net impact of trade liberalization might be<br />

masked because of the interaction between institution and trade.<br />

5. Conclusion<br />

In <strong>Vietnam</strong>, the transition from command to mixed economy and the concomitant opening to<br />

international trade and investment has seen real wages and returns to schooling both rise as expected.<br />

These trends have been well documented. The contribution of this paper is first to identify distinct<br />

phases of change in wages and intersectoral wage premia, and second, to begin the task of explaining<br />

them. Mincerian regressions and wage growth decompositions of the kind that we have reported and<br />

discussed in the first part of this paper can document changes that have occurred over time, but do not<br />

tell us much about the reasons for them. Indeed, the large “change in coefficients” component of the<br />

decomposition analysis for wage growth (Table 4) simply reveals the extent of our ignorance of<br />

underlying causal factors.


15<br />

Each individual’s wage is determined by his or her own characteristics as well as by broader forces<br />

operating on labor markets. In a small transition economy like <strong>Vietnam</strong>, these broader forces are<br />

increasingly dominated by global influences through trade, and the momentum of domestic policy<br />

reforms—notably, though not exclusively, those specifically targeting the operation of labor markets.<br />

Our approach has been to designate trade policy and domestic market reforms as ‘treatments’ imposed<br />

on an economy where, for historical and institutional reasons, state sector and private sector labor<br />

markets are substantively segmented, general equilibrium labor market constraints notwithstanding.<br />

With this approach we are able, using a triple-­‐difference estimator, to identify the contributions of each<br />

type of policy change to changes in wages, and to changes in intersectoral wage premia, in different<br />

phases of the economic reform process.<br />

The results, though preliminary, are intriguing. In the early reform years, the public sector (mainly state-­‐<br />

owned enterprises) was substantially shielded from the process of economic liberalization. State-­‐owned<br />

firms and industries remained the beneficiaries of many privileges that made them attractive partners<br />

for early foreign capital inflows and joint-­‐venture production arrangements. So trade liberalization in<br />

the 1990s raised the premium to state sector workers in tradable industries; these gains were<br />

augmented by domestic reforms that liberalized the state sector labor market, allowing wages in this<br />

sector to rise. Also, because state firms tend to be very skill-­‐intensive, 10 this might have contributed to<br />

the rise in returns to skill of state sector workers. At the same time, the laying off of a large number of<br />

state workers during the 1990s might have increased the supply of skilled labor to the private sector,<br />

causing returns to skill in the private sector to not increase by as much. In short, the rapid increase in<br />

returns to skill in the 1990s was mostly driven by the increase in skill premia in the state sector rather<br />

than in the private sector.<br />

In later years, the momentum of trade and investment began to shift (albeit gradually) toward private<br />

sector firms. This slowed the increase in public sector premium relative to private sector premium. But<br />

investments in the expansion of private sector activity were motivated much more by the desire to<br />

exploit <strong>Vietnam</strong>’s comparative abundance of unskilled workers; hence, returns to skill in the private<br />

sector remained rather low, an outcome of the Heckscher-­‐Ohlin effect. This result, coupled with the<br />

increased importance of private sector employment, yielded the net effect that the skill premium in the<br />

overall labor market flattened out in the 2000s (the effect of the private sector skill premium now<br />

dominates that of the public sector skill premium). Our triple-­‐difference analysis has quantified wage<br />

changes and changes in intersectoral wage premia within a unified econometric framework. Knowing<br />

that state sectors are more skill-­‐intensive by virtue of their special policy treatment, our results then<br />

contribute to a deeper understanding of the skill premium trends shown in Figure 1.<br />

The flattening of the skill premium, if maintained, has potentially important development implications.<br />

On one hand, decreased skill premia associated with the increased specialization in labor-­‐intensive<br />

industries should reduce wage inequality. On the other hand, a lower skill premium reduces incentives<br />

10 In another paper which we use Enterprise Survey 2007, we have been able to show that state firms tend to be<br />

much more skill-intensive than private firms. Higher degree of capital-intensity contributes to higher skilledunskilled<br />

relative labor demand for state firms, but it contributes to less skilled-unskilled relative labor demand for<br />

private firms.


16<br />

to accumulate human capital, which will hinder long-­‐term economic growth to the extent that this<br />

depends on steady progress up the quality (and thus skill-­‐intensity) ladder. To offset the effects of<br />

globalization-­‐driven changes from the demand side of the market for skills requires policy reforms and<br />

investments that address supply, mainly through improvements in the quality, quantity and affordability<br />

of education. At the same time, there is a large growth dividend associated with the further relaxation<br />

of special treatment for SOEs. As a group, these industries absorb a large share of <strong>Vietnam</strong>’s investment<br />

capital and skilled labor, yet they are highly inefficient and their activities contribute relatively little to<br />

overall income growth. 11<br />

11 To illustrate, CIEM estimates a state-sector ICOR of 17.5 as opposed to a private sector ICOR of 4.6 (cited in<br />

Asia Times: “<strong>Vietnam</strong> changes course”, <strong>April</strong> 12 <strong>2011</strong>,<br />

http://www.atimes.com/atimes/Southeast_Asia/MD12Ae01.html).


17<br />

Table 1: Mean hourly wages (thousand VND)<br />

1993 1998 2002 2004 2006 2008<br />

all 1.83 2.90 3.83 4.54 4.56 7.34<br />

Gini 0.38 0.35 0.42 0.36 0.35 0.39<br />

men 2.07 3.10 3.99 4.74 4.77 7.62<br />

women 1.49 2.59 3.57 4.22 4.23 6.91<br />

men/women ratio 1.39 1.20 1.12 1.12 1.13 1.10<br />

T-­‐stat for diff. in mean b/t men & women 6.95 5.16 5.40 5.62 5.50 3.78<br />

rural 1.80 2.46 2.96 3.69 4.02 5.99<br />

urban 1.87 3.53 5.46 5.82 5.38 9.38<br />

urban/rural ratio 1.04 1.43 1.84 1.57 1.34 1.56<br />

T-­‐stat for diff. in mean b/t rural & urban 0.86 12.65 24.62 18.80 13.25 16.40<br />

Kinh 1.84 2.95 3.98 4.61 4.63 7.44<br />

minority 1.70 2.27 2.22 3.43 3.53 5.73<br />

Kinh/minority ratio 1.08 1.30 1.79 1.34 1.31 1.30<br />

T-­‐stat for diff. in mean b/t Kinh & minority 0.80 3.47 9.20 4.45 4.40 3.51<br />

Public 1.71 3.23 5.49 5.64 5.61 9.34<br />

Non-­‐public 1.89 2.73 3.<strong>14</strong> 3.60 3.65 5.84<br />

Public/nonpublic ratio 0.90 1.18 1.75 1.57 1.54 1.60<br />

T-­‐stat for diff. in mean b/t public & private 2.08 5.95 25.24 21.70 21.75 20.28<br />

no degree 1.76 2.53 2.54 3.07 3.13 4.80<br />

primary school degree 1.99 2.68 3.03 3.50 3.53 5.39<br />

middle school degree 1.74 2.68 3.72 3.92 3.89 5.60<br />

high school degree 1.75 3.20 4.70 5.42 4.99 7.82<br />

college degree and higher 2.03 5.36 7.37 8.08 8.42 <strong>14</strong>.74<br />

T-­‐stat for diff. in mean b/t primary degree & others 2.32 4.57 10.59 12.37 12.16 10.64<br />

T-­‐stat for diff. in mean b/t middle school degree & others 1.34 3.48 3.24 7.24 8.02 9.89<br />

T-­‐stat for diff. in mean b/t high school degree & others 0.88 2.54 8.82 9.32 5.97 3.74<br />

T-­‐stat for diff. in mean b/t college degree & others 1.25 17.73 28.00 27.74 32.60 32.18<br />

NOTE: all wages have been deflated to January 1998 prices


Table 2: Average annual growth in wages<br />

1993-­‐<br />

1998<br />

1998-­‐<br />

2002<br />

2002-­‐<br />

2008<br />

18<br />

1993-­‐<br />

2008<br />

All 12% 8% 15% 20%<br />

Men 10% 7% 15% 18%<br />

Women 15% 10% 16% 24%<br />

rural 7% 5% 17% 16%<br />

urban 18% <strong>14</strong>% 12% 27%<br />

Kinh 12% 9% <strong>14</strong>% 20%<br />

minority 7% -­‐1% 26% 16%<br />

Public 18% 17% 12% 30%<br />

Private 9% 4% <strong>14</strong>% <strong>14</strong>%<br />

no degree 9% 0% 15% 12%<br />

primary 7% 3% 13% 11%<br />

lower 11% 10% 8% 15%<br />

upper 17% 12% 11% 23%<br />

college 33% 9% 17% 42%<br />

3.50<br />

3.00<br />

2.50<br />

2.00<br />

1.50<br />

1.00<br />

0.50<br />

0.00<br />

Figure 1: <strong>Vietnam</strong>'s skill premium 1993-­‐2008<br />

(relaPve wage to workers with no degree)<br />

1993 1998 2002 2004 2006 2008<br />

primary school degree middle school degree<br />

high school degree college degree and higher


Table 3a: Determinants of <strong>Wage</strong> – OLS Estimation Results Specification 1<br />

Dependent variable: log(hourly wage) 1993 1998 2002 2004 2006 2008<br />

Years of education 0.004 0.032 0.036 0.040 0.048 0.051<br />

Years of experience 0.017 0.023 0.022 0.038 0.035 0.036<br />

Years of experience squared 0.000 0.000 0.000 -­‐0.001 0.000 -­‐0.001<br />

Male dummy 0.295 0.167 0.179 0.170 0.178 0.192<br />

Ethnic minority dummy -­‐0.029 -­‐0.003 -­‐0.351 -­‐0.108 -­‐0.065 -­‐0.063<br />

Urban dummy 0.072 0.182 0.251 0.153 0.037 0.<strong>14</strong>7<br />

Public sector dummy -­‐0.120 -­‐0.105 0.245 0.137 0.151 0.<strong>14</strong>2<br />

Tradable industry dummy 0.026 -­‐0.010 -­‐0.106 -­‐0.009 0.002 -­‐0.031<br />

Constant 0.051 0.326 0.467 0.596 0.807 1.133<br />

N 2608 3590 2<strong>14</strong>51 6639 6901 7019<br />

Adjusted R-­‐squared 0.06 0.13 0.25 0.27 0.29 0.29<br />

Notes: Bold means statistically significant at 5% or less<br />

Italic means statistically significant at 10%<br />

Standard errors are robust and adjusted for clustering<br />

Table 3b: Determinants of <strong>Wage</strong> – OLS Estimation Results Specification 2<br />

Dependent variable: log(hourly wage) 1993 1998 2002 2004 2006 2008<br />

Primary school degree 0.011 0.037 0.064 0.080 0.101 0.078<br />

Middle school degree -­‐0.097 0.023 0.081 0.089 0.157 0.098<br />

High school degree -­‐0.036 0.182 0.257 0.292 0.320 0.306<br />

College degree and above 0.175 0.546 0.610 0.630 0.736 0.813<br />

Years of experience 0.017 0.021 0.023 0.035 0.032 0.033<br />

Years of experience squared 0.000 0.000 -­‐0.001 -­‐0.001 0.000 -­‐0.001<br />

Male dummy 0.294 0.176 0.190 0.191 0.196 0.2<strong>14</strong><br />

Ethnic minority dummy -­‐0.058 -­‐0.067 -­‐0.390 -­‐0.132 -­‐0.095 -­‐0.097<br />

Urban dummy 0.073 0.180 0.244 0.<strong>14</strong>0 0.026 0.119<br />

Public sector dummy -­‐0.113 -­‐0.103 0.210 0.120 0.137 0.122<br />

Tradable industry dummy 0.033 -­‐0.001 -­‐0.104 -­‐0.007 0.005 -­‐0.022<br />

Constant 0.097 0.505 0.613 0.784 1.026 1.402<br />

N 2608 3590 2<strong>14</strong>51 6639 6901 7019<br />

Adjusted R-­‐squared 0.07 0.<strong>14</strong> 0.26 0.29 0.31 0.32<br />

Notes: Bold means statistically significant at 5% or less<br />

Italic means statistically significant at 10%<br />

Standard errors are robust and adjusted for clustering<br />

19


20<br />

Table 4: Oaxaca-­‐Blinder Decomposition of Sources of <strong>Wage</strong> Growth<br />

Δlog(wage)<br />

1993-­‐1998 1998-­‐2002 2002-­‐2008<br />

%<br />

contribution Δlog(wage)<br />

%<br />

contribution Δlog(wage)<br />

%<br />

contribution<br />

Observed total increase in log(wage) 0.543 0.217 0.933<br />

Due to increase in base wage 0.275 50.7% 0.<strong>14</strong>1 64.9% 0.666 71.4%<br />

Due to changes in characteristics 0.028 5.2% 0.024 11.2% 0.023 2.5%<br />

Years of education 0.0<strong>14</strong> 2.6% -­‐0.004 -­‐1.8% 0.046 5.0%<br />

Years of experience 0.003 0.6% 0.136 62.4% -­‐0.191 -­‐20.5%<br />

Years of experience squared -­‐0.001 -­‐0.2% -­‐0.091 -­‐41.7% 0.124 13.3%<br />

Male dummy 0.002 0.5% 0.002 0.9% -­‐0.001 -­‐0.1%<br />

Ethnic minority dummy 0.000 0.0% -­‐0.011 -­‐5.1% 0.006 0.6%<br />

Urban dummy 0.015 2.7% -­‐0.035 -­‐15.9% 0.007 0.8%<br />

Public sector dummy -­‐0.004 -­‐0.7% -­‐0.012 -­‐5.6% 0.024 2.6%<br />

Tradable industry dummy -­‐0.001 -­‐0.2% 0.000 0.2% 0.008 0.9%<br />

Due to changes in returns to<br />

characteristics 0.240 44.1% 0.091 41.8% 0.244 26.1%<br />

Years of education 0.229 42.2% 0.028 13.1% 0.<strong>14</strong>2 15.2%<br />

Years of experience 0.046 8.5% -­‐0.008 -­‐3.7% 0.139 <strong>14</strong>.9%<br />

Years of experience squared 0.008 1.4% -­‐0.028 -­‐13.1% -­‐0.021 -­‐2.3%<br />

Male dummy -­‐0.076 -­‐<strong>14</strong>.0% 0.007 3.1% 0.008 0.8%<br />

Kinh ethnicity dummy 0.002 0.3% -­‐0.021 -­‐9.7% 0.022 2.4%<br />

Urban dummy 0.046 8.5% 0.033 15.1% -­‐0.039 -­‐4.2%<br />

Public sector dummy 0.006 1.0% 0.131 60.4% -­‐0.042 -­‐4.5%<br />

Tradable industry dummy -­‐0.021 -­‐3.8% -­‐0.051 -­‐23.5% 0.035 3.7%<br />

Notes: Bold means statistically significant at 5% or less<br />

Italic means statistically significant at 10%<br />

Table 5: average hourly wage by educational level and institution, 1993<br />

Public Nonpublic Public/Ratio<br />

no degree 1.89 1.75 1.08<br />

primary school 1.85 2.02 0.92<br />

lower secondary 1.54 1.88 0.82<br />

upper secondary 1.63 2.01 0.81<br />

college & above 2.04 1.90 1.07<br />

<strong>Wage</strong> ratio (base = no degree)<br />

no degree 1 1<br />

primary school 0.98 1.16<br />

middle school 0.82 1.07<br />

high school 0.86 1.15<br />

college & above 1.08 1.09<br />

<strong>Wage</strong>s are in thousand VND, January 1993 price, deflated regionally and monthly


21<br />

Table 6: returns to education in public vs. private sectors<br />

1993 1998 2002 2008<br />

public private public private public private public private<br />

primary -­‐0.084 0.116 -­‐0.002 0.051 0.038 0.068 0.015 0.065<br />

middle -­‐0.165 0.118 0.020 0.066 0.134 0.078 0.076 0.126<br />

high -­‐0.031 0.109 0.<strong>14</strong>5 0.171 0.252 0.216 0.398 0.211<br />

college 0.251 0.272 0.505 0.875 0.557 0.600 0.764 0.581<br />

educ_yrs 0.029 0.018 0.053 0.023 0.053 0.019 0.081 0.024<br />

Notes: Bold means statistically significant at 5% or less<br />

Italic means statistically significant at 10%<br />

OLS regressions with robust and clustering adjusted standard errors<br />

Other covariates (experience, gender, ethnicity, urban, trade) were included but not reported<br />

Table 7: structure of employment<br />

1993 1998 2002 2004 2006 2008<br />

Self employed 73.9% 59.1% 63.9% 60.7% 58.7% 58.3%<br />

<strong>Wage</strong> employed 26.1% 40.9% 36.1% 39.3% 41.3% 41.7%<br />

Public 5.8% 7.1% 9.3% 13.3% <strong>14</strong>.2% 13.6%<br />

Private 20.3% 33.7% 26.8% 26.0% 27.1% 28.1%<br />

Table 8: Difference in Differences in Differences Estimation<br />

Dependent variable: log(hourly wage)<br />

1993 &<br />

1998<br />

1998 &<br />

2002<br />

2002 &<br />

2008<br />

Later year dummy (a1) 0.527 0.171 0.857<br />

trade (a2) 0.057 -­‐0.009 -­‐0.<strong>14</strong>3<br />

public (a3) -­‐0.228 -­‐0.<strong>14</strong>2 0.168<br />

Later year * trade (b1) -­‐0.131 -­‐0.<strong>14</strong>0 0.111<br />

trade * public (b2) 0.004 0.066 0.137<br />

Later year * public (b3) 0.135 0.336 0.052<br />

Later year * trade * public (c ) 0.107 0.061 -­‐0.171<br />

Years of education 0.022 0.036 0.041<br />

Years of experience 0.021 0.023 0.026<br />

Years of experience squared 0.000 -­‐0.001 -­‐0.001<br />

Male dummy 0.218 0.171 0.176<br />

Kinh ethnicity dummy -­‐0.007 -­‐0.307 -­‐0.278<br />

Urban dummy 0.139 0.230 0.217<br />

Constant -­‐0.090 0.317 0.420<br />

Notes: Bold means statistically significant at 5% or less<br />

Italic means statistically significant at 10%<br />

OLS regressions with robust and clustering adjusted standard errors


22<br />

Table 9: Determinants of <strong>Wage</strong> -­‐ Heckman Estimation Results<br />

<strong>Wage</strong> equation (dependent variable = log wage)<br />

1993 1998 2002 2004 2006 2008<br />

Years of education 0.011 0.039 0.037 0.043 0.052 0.057<br />

Years of experience 0.016 0.023 0.023 0.039 0.035 0.037<br />

Years of experience squared 0.000 0.000 -­‐0.001 -­‐0.001 0.000 -­‐0.001<br />

Male dummy 0.390 0.3<strong>14</strong> 0.219 0.210 0.220 0.244<br />

Ethnicity minority dummy -­‐0.1<strong>14</strong> -­‐0.137 -­‐0.387 -­‐0.159 -­‐0.121 -­‐0.<strong>14</strong>6<br />

Urban dummy 0.226 0.403 0.292 0.192 0.081 0.194<br />

Public sector dummy -­‐0.121 -­‐0.100 0.243 0.136 0.<strong>14</strong>8 0.138<br />

Tradable industry dummy 0.027 -­‐0.007 -­‐0.106 -­‐0.008 0.002 -­‐0.033<br />

Constant -­‐0.606 -­‐0.608 0.254 0.378 0.555 0.815<br />

Selection equation<br />

Years of education 0.027 0.025 0.028 0.044 0.045 0.050<br />

Male dummy 0.327 0.345 0.384 0.396 0.360 0.372<br />

Ethnic minority dummy -­‐0.278 -­‐0.302 -­‐0.364 -­‐0.529 -­‐0.482 -­‐0.574<br />

Urban dummy 0.539 0.578 0.457 0.420 0.415 0.369<br />

Dependency ratio -­‐0.033 0.049 0.091 0.068 0.079 0.139<br />

Log (non-­‐wage income) -­‐ -­‐ -­‐0.173 -­‐0.205 -­‐0.203 -­‐0.126<br />

Dummy for head of household 0.042 0.067 0.053 0.022 0.040 0.038<br />

Age -­‐0.004 -­‐0.003 -­‐0.001 -­‐0.001 -­‐0.001 0.000<br />

Constant -­‐1.176 -­‐1.268 -­‐0.974 -­‐1.111 -­‐1.121 -­‐1.249<br />

N 12985 16689 8<strong>14</strong>62 25656 25703 25530<br />

Rho 0.508 0.729 0.206 0.242 0.298 0.327<br />

Sigma 0.747 0.744 0.679 0.552 0.529 0.597<br />

Lamda 0.379 0.542 0.<strong>14</strong>0 0.133 0.158 0.195<br />

Chi2 for Wald test that rho=0 2.25 95.62 29.18 6.95 5.00 3.03<br />

Notes: Bold means statistically significant at 5% or less<br />

Italic means statistically significant at 10%<br />

All regressions have robust and clustering adjusted standard errors


References<br />

Arbache, J. A. Dickerson and F. Green (2004) “Trade liberalization and wages in developing countries”<br />

The Economic Journal Vol. 1<strong>14</strong>, pp. F73-­‐F96<br />

Athukorala, Prema-­‐chandra (2006) "Trade Policy Reforms and the Structure of Protection in<br />

<strong>Vietnam</strong>," The World Economy, Blackwell Publishing, vol. 29(2), pages 161-­‐187, 02<br />

23<br />

Prema-­‐chandra Athukorala & Tran Quang Tien, 2009. "Foreign Direct Investment in Industrial Transition:<br />

The Experience of <strong>Vietnam</strong>," Departmental Working <strong>Paper</strong>s 2009-­‐20, Australian National University,<br />

Arndt-­‐Corden Department of Economics<br />

Cai, Y, A. Park, and F. Zhou (2008). “The Chinese Labor Market in the Reform Era.” In Loren Brandt and<br />

Thomas Rawski, eds., China’s Great Economic Transformation (Cambridge University Press).<br />

Card, D (2008) "Returns to schooling." The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online, eds. S.N.<br />

Durlauf and L.E. Blume. Palgrave Macmillan. 03 <strong>April</strong> <strong>2011</strong>.<br />

Doan, Tinh and John Gibson (2010) “Return to schooling in <strong>Vietnam</strong> during economic transition: does<br />

the return reach its peak?” MPRA <strong>Paper</strong> #24984, Economics Department, University of Waikato<br />

Feenstra, Robert and Gordon Hanson (1997) “Foreign Direct Investments and Relative <strong>Wage</strong>s: Evidence<br />

from Mexico’s Maquiladoras,” Journal of International Economics Vol. 42, pp. 371-­‐94.<br />

Gallup, John L. (2002) “The <strong>Wage</strong> Labor Market and Inequality in Viet Nam in the 1990s,” World Bank<br />

Policy Research Working <strong>Paper</strong> #2896<br />

Goujon, A. & Samir K. C. (2006). Past and future of human capital in SE Asia: 1970-­‐2030. Vienna Institute<br />

of Demography, Working <strong>Paper</strong>s, 07/ 2006.<br />

Hausman, R., J. Hwang, and D. Rodrik (2007). “What you export matters.” Journal of Economic Growth<br />

12(1): 1-­‐25.<br />

Imbert, Clement (2010) “Decomposing <strong>Wage</strong> Inequality: Public and Private Sectors in <strong>Vietnam</strong> 1993-­‐<br />

2006” PSE-­‐Paris School of Economics, available at http://mitsloan.mit.edu/neudc/papers/paper_244.pdf<br />

(accessed <strong>April</strong> 12 <strong>2011</strong>)<br />

Jenkins, Rhys (2004) “Why has employment not grown more quickly in <strong>Vietnam</strong>?” Journal of Asia Pacific<br />

Economy 9(2) 2004: 191-­‐208<br />

Jenkins, Rhys (2002) “Globalization, FDI and employment in <strong>Vietnam</strong>” Transnational Corporation 15(1),<br />

pp. 115-­‐<strong>14</strong>2, 2006<br />

Knight, John, and Lina Song. 2003. “Increasing urban wage inequality in China: Extent, elements and<br />

evaluation.” Economies of Transition 11: 597-­‐619.<br />

Liu, A. Y.C. (2006) “Changing wage structure and education in <strong>Vietnam</strong> 1993-­‐1998: The roles of demand”<br />

Journal of Transition, <strong>14</strong>(4): 681-­‐706


Liu, A. Y.C. (2005) “Impact of economic reform on wage structure in Viet Nam” East Asian Economic<br />

Perspectives, 16(2): 46-­‐57.<br />

24<br />

Liu, A. Y.C. (2004a) “Changes in gender wage gap in <strong>Vietnam</strong>”, Journal of Comparative Economics 32(3):<br />

586-­‐596.<br />

Liu, A. Y.C. (2004b) “Sectoral gender wage gap in <strong>Vietnam</strong>” Oxford Development Studies 32(4): 225-­‐239<br />

Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. New York: NBER (distributed by Columbia<br />

University Press).<br />

Moock, P R., H.A. Patrinos, and M. Venkataraman (2003). “Education and earnings in a transition<br />

economy: the case of <strong>Vietnam</strong>.” Economics of Education Review 22(5): 503-­‐510.<br />

Nguyen, Cong Gian, Doan, Hong Quang, Nguyen, Thi Lan Huong, and Remco H. Oostendorp (2006)<br />

“Trade Liberalization, The Gender <strong>Wage</strong> Gap, and Returns to Education in <strong>Vietnam</strong>” Working <strong>Paper</strong><br />

available at http://vern.org.vn/rs/Document/Gender%20<strong>Wage</strong>%20Gap.pdf (accessed <strong>April</strong> 12 <strong>2011</strong>)<br />

Oostendorp, Remco H. and Doan, Hong Quang (2010) “The Impact of Trade Liberalization on the Return<br />

to Education in <strong>Vietnam</strong>: <strong>Wage</strong> versus Employment Effect” Tinbergen Institute Discussion <strong>Paper</strong> <strong>2011</strong>-­‐<br />

060/3<br />

Pham, Hung and Reilley Barry (2007a) “The Gender Pay Gap in <strong>Vietnam</strong>, 1993-­‐2002: A Quintile<br />

Regression Approach,” Journal of Asian Economics 185(5): 775-­‐806<br />

Pham, Hung and Reilley Barry (2007b) “Ethnic <strong>Wage</strong> Inequality in <strong>Vietnam</strong>: Empirical Evidence from<br />

2002” MPRA Working <strong>Paper</strong> #6477, Department of Economics, University of Sussex, November,<br />

available at http://mpra.ub.uni-­‐muenchen.de/6477/1/MPRA_paper_6477.pdf (accessed <strong>April</strong> 12 <strong>2011</strong>)<br />

Sakellariou, Chris and Zheng Fang (2010) “After the Reforms: Determinants of <strong>Wage</strong> Growth and Change<br />

in <strong>Wage</strong> Inequality in <strong>Vietnam</strong> 1998-­‐2008” Working <strong>Paper</strong> #1020/06, Economic Growth Centre, Division<br />

of Economics, School of Humanities and Social Sciences, Nanyang Technological University<br />

Wood, Adrian (1997) “Openness and <strong>Wage</strong> Inequality in Developing Countries: The Latin American<br />

Challenge to East Asian Conventional Wisdom” World Bank Economic Review 11(1), pp. 33-­‐57.<br />

World Bank (1995). Viet Nam: Economic Report on Industrialization and Industrial Policy. Country<br />

Operations Division, East Asia and Pacific Region, Country Report No. <strong>14</strong>645-­‐VN.<br />

Zhu, Chun, and Daniel. Trefler (2005) “Trade and inequality in developing countries: A general<br />

equilibrium analysis.” Journal of International Economics Vol. 65, pp. 21-­‐48.


Appendix A: Data Notes<br />

25<br />

The primary source of data is the <strong>Vietnam</strong>ese Living Standard Surveys (VLSS 1993 and 1998, and VHLSS<br />

2002, 2004, 2006, and 2008). These are all standard World-­‐Bank-­‐type income and expenditure<br />

household survey, designed to study living conditions and poverty and inequality issues. They have<br />

employment modules that produce employment and wage data used in this paper. The earlier rounds<br />

(VLSS 1993 and 1998) were smaller in size (4,800 and 6,000 households respectively) and were<br />

representative at the national, rural/urban, and regional levels. The survey year 2002 had the most<br />

number of households at 29533. For the last there rounds, the number of households stayed constant at<br />

9189.<br />

In our empirical work, we include all individuals in the working age (15-­‐60 years of age) with reported<br />

wages. Hourly wage (thousand VND per hours worked) is calculated by dividing annual total wage (main<br />

salary plus other bonuses and cash benefits) by the estimated number of hours work during the year.<br />

Only the primary job is counted. Within each survey year, wages are regionally deflated to the January<br />

of the year using the provided deflators in the surveys (rcpi and mcpi). For year 2002, there are no data<br />

on experience. So we replace it with the minimum of age-­‐17 and age – schooling years – 17.<br />

Most other papers that use the VHLSS data use the survey’s original schooling year variable, which<br />

ranges from 0 through 12 years only. In our paper, we adjusted education years for highest educational<br />

level (a junior college degree means <strong>14</strong> years of education, a college degree 16 years of education,<br />

master degree 18 years, and PhD 22 years). As a result, average years of schooling that we present are<br />

higher than that found in most other studies also using the VHLSS. This might also lead to lower<br />

estimates of returns to schooling years.


Appendix B: Tradable and Non-­‐tradable Industry List<br />

26<br />

Non-­‐tradable industries include industries numbered 37 through 73, 75 through 91, and 93 through 98.<br />

The rest are tradable industries. This definition is based on examining UN’s COMTRADE data. If an<br />

industry does not show up in COMTRADE data, it’s considered non-­‐tradable. All agricultural, mining, and<br />

manufacturing (except recycling) industries are in COMTRADE. Most utility and service industries do not,<br />

except 40 (electricity, gas, and water), 74 (other business activities), 92 (disposable collection and public<br />

sanitation), and 99 (foreign organization activities).<br />

industry code<br />

Agriculture and sylviculture<br />

01 Agriculture and relating services (including livestock raising)<br />

02 Sylviculture and relating services<br />

Aquaculture<br />

05 Catching and raising seaproducts, and relating services<br />

mining industry<br />

10 Coal mining<br />

11 Oil and gas drilling and related services<br />

(except: exploring/searching activities)<br />

12 Uranium and Thorium mining<br />

13 Metal mining<br />

<strong>14</strong> Mining for rocks, stone, sand, salt, fertilizer...<br />

Processing industry<br />

15 Food and beverage production<br />

16 Tobacco production<br />

17 Textile<br />

18 Fur processing and fur products (excluding garments)<br />

19 Leather tanning and leather products including wallets, seats,<br />

suitcases<br />

20 Wood, bamboo, rattan processing and production of wood,<br />

bamboo and rattan products<br />

21 <strong>Paper</strong> and paper products<br />

22 Printing and publishing (books, magazines, newspapers, and<br />

23 Coke, crude oil, uranium processing<br />

24 Chemicals and chemical products<br />

25 Plastic and Rubber production and products<br />

26 Other non-metal mineral products production<br />

27 Metal production and processing<br />

28 Metal products (except machines and equipment)<br />

29 Other equipment and machinery not specified elsewhere<br />

30 Office and computer equipment production<br />

31 Other electronic, electric equipment not specified elsewhere<br />

32 Radio, TV, broadcasting and other communication equipment<br />

33 Medical and laboratory equipment, precision instruments, and meters (clocks)<br />

34 Motor vehicles and spare parts<br />

35 Other means of transportation (boats, railroad, airplane)<br />

36 Furniture production and other productions not specified elsewhere<br />

37 Recycling, reprocessing


27<br />

Electricity, gas, and water production and distribution<br />

40 Electricity, gas, water steam, hot water production and distribution<br />

41 Water exploitation, purification, and distribution<br />

Construction<br />

45 Construction<br />

trading; repairation of motor vehicles and motorbikes<br />

private and household tools<br />

50 Vehicle sales, maintenance and repair; retail sale of gas<br />

51 Wholesale and agent sales (excluding motor vehicles and motorbikes)<br />

Retail sales (excluding motor vehicles and motorbikes);repairs of family<br />

52 appliances<br />

55<br />

hotel and restaurant<br />

Hotel and restaurant (including big and small restaurants, cafe, beverage and<br />

drink stands,...)<br />

transportation, warehouse/ storage site, communication<br />

60 Road, railroad and pipeline transport<br />

61 Water transport<br />

62 Airline transport<br />

63 Services in transport; tourist services<br />

64 Post and telecommunications<br />

Finance and credit<br />

65 Financial intermediary (excluding insurance and social welfare)<br />

66 Insurance and pensions (excluding social insurance)<br />

67 Assistance in finance (including social insurance)<br />

Science and technology activities<br />

70 Science and technology activities<br />

Activities relating asset businesses and consulting services<br />

71 Activities relating real-estate<br />

Rental of machines and equipment (excluding operators); rental of furnitures<br />

72 and household goods<br />

73 Computer-related activities<br />

74 Other business activities (accounting, tax and other consulting,<br />

architecture, advertising, protection, housecleaning, photography, packaging,<br />

etc.<br />

Government administration and national defense; promulgated social ensurance<br />

75 Government administration and national defense; promulgated social ensurance<br />

Education and training<br />

80 Education and training<br />

85<br />

90<br />

health and social relief<br />

Health and social relief (hospitals, health centers, veterinary care, social<br />

relief,...)<br />

Cultural and sport activities<br />

Cultural and sport activities (broadcasting, television, cinema, recreation<br />

and entertainment, press, library,<br />

museum, sport,...)<br />

Communist party, mass organizations, professional associations<br />

91 Communist party, mass organizations, professional associations<br />

Public and personal services<br />

92 Disposal collection, public sanitation improvement, and similar activities<br />

93 Other service activities (laundry, hairdressing, funerals,…)<br />

housework services provided at client's home


28<br />

95 Housework services provided at client's home<br />

Activities of foreign organizations<br />

99 Activities of foreign organizations

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!