22.04.2013 Views

Economic Equilibrium Modeling with GAMS

Economic Equilibrium Modeling with GAMS

Economic Equilibrium Modeling with GAMS

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

4<br />

Figure 1. An Indi erence Curve<br />

Y<br />

4<br />

1<br />

1 3<br />

on the preferences of a single consumer, the indi erence curve is a line which connects<br />

all combinations of two goods x and y between which our consumer is indi erent. As<br />

this curve is drawn, we have represented an agent <strong>with</strong> well-behaved preferences: at<br />

any allocation, more is better (monotonicity), and averages are preferred to extremes<br />

(convexity). Exactly one indi erence curve goes through each positive combination of x<br />

and y. Higher indi erence curves lie to the north-east.<br />

If we wish to characterize an agent's preferences, the marginal rate of substitution<br />

(MRS) is a useful point of reference. At a given combination of x and y, the marginal<br />

rate of substitution is the slope of the associated indi erence curve. As drawn, the MRS<br />

increases in magnitude as we move to the northwest and the MRS decreases as we move<br />

to the south east. The intuitive understanding is that the MRS measures the willingness<br />

of the consumer to trade o one good for the other. As the consumer has greater amounts<br />

of x, she will be willing to trade more units of x for each additional unit of y { this results<br />

from convexity.<br />

An ordinal utility function U(x; y) provides a helpful tool for representing preferences.<br />

This is a function which associates a number <strong>with</strong> each indi erence curve. These numbers<br />

increase as we move to the northeast, <strong>with</strong> each successive indi erence curve representing<br />

bundles which are preferred over the last. The particular number assigned to an indi erence<br />

curve has no intrinsic meaning. All we know is that if U(x1;y1) > U(x2;y2), then the<br />

consumer prefers bundle 1 to bundle 2.<br />

Figure 2 illustrates how it is possible to use a utility function to generate a diagram<br />

<strong>with</strong> the associated indi erence curves. This gure illustrates Cobb-Douglas well-behaved<br />

preferences which are commonly employed in applied work.<br />

Up to this point, we have wehave focused exclusively on the characterization of preferences.<br />

Let us now consider the other side of the consumer model { the budget constraint.<br />

The simplest approach tocharacterizing consumer income is to assume that the consumer<br />

has a xed money income which she may spend on any goods. The only constraint on this<br />

choice is that the value of the expenditure may not exceed the money income. This is the<br />

standard budget constraint:<br />

Pxx + Pyy = M:<br />

X

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!