03.06.2013 Views

EU Competition Law and Policy - compal

EU Competition Law and Policy - compal

EU Competition Law and Policy - compal

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Rebates<br />

©Ariel Ezrachi, December 2012<br />

P a g e | 12<br />

The European law concerning rebates generally distinguishes between quantity discounts, which<br />

are linked solely to the volume of purchases from the manufacturer concerned, <strong>and</strong> loyalty<br />

inducing rebates. Whereas the former are considered valuable <strong>and</strong> acceptable components of<br />

price competition, the latter are held to be abusive. The traditional analysis of loyalty rebates, as<br />

evident from the cases below, has been criticised as too formalistic, failing to take into account<br />

the effects different discount schemes have on competition. In its Guidance Paper, the<br />

European Commission has advanced a more nuanced ‘effects-based approach’. That approach<br />

was manifested, to some extent, in the Commission’s decisions in Prokent/Tomra <strong>and</strong> Intel<br />

Corporation. However, the Court of Justice of the European Union has yet to endorse it (T-<br />

155/06, appeal pending C-549/10 P).<br />

85/76 Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. v Commission<br />

322/81 Nederl<strong>and</strong>sche B<strong>and</strong>en Industrie Michelin v Commission<br />

T-203/01 Manufacture française des pneumatiques Michelin v Commission<br />

T-219/99 British Airways v Commission<br />

C-95/04 British Airways v Commission<br />

T-155/06 Tomra Systems <strong>and</strong> Others v Commission<br />

COMP/C-3/37.990 Intel Corporation<br />

T-66/01 Imperial Chemical Industries Ltd v Commission<br />

Margin Squeeze<br />

Margin squeeze (also known as price squeeze) refers to a situation where a vertically integrated<br />

dominant undertaking engages in a strategy which aims to favour its own downstream<br />

operations. The strategy may, for example, take place when the dominant undertaking supplies<br />

input both to its own downstream operation <strong>and</strong> to other competitors in the downstream market<br />

<strong>and</strong> increases the price charged to competitor, to squeeze their profit <strong>and</strong> improve the position<br />

of its own downstream operation.<br />

C-280/08 P Deutsche Telekom AG v Commission<br />

1016/1/1/03 Genzyme Limited v Office of Fair Trading<br />

COMP/38.784 Wanadoo España v Telefónica<br />

C-52/09 Konkurrensverket v TeliaSonera Sverige AB<br />

Excessive Pricing<br />

A dominant undertaking may choose to take advantage of its market power <strong>and</strong> increase the<br />

price of its products above competitive levels. Such practice may amount to an abuse of a<br />

dominant position when it involves the imposition of unfair purchase or selling prices or the<br />

application of dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions.<br />

Excessive prices may be analysed using two of the sub-sections in Article 102 TF<strong>EU</strong>. Under<br />

Article 102(a) TF<strong>EU</strong> they may be challenged when they consist of: ‘directly or indirectly<br />

imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions’. Under Article<br />

102(c) TF<strong>EU</strong> they may be objected to when they result in a discriminatory practice. The<br />

following cases provide an illustration of the Commission’s <strong>and</strong> European Courts’ approach to<br />

excessive prices:<br />

26/75 General Motors v Commission

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!