22.06.2013 Views

CHAPTER 3 Consumer Preferences and Choice

CHAPTER 3 Consumer Preferences and Choice

CHAPTER 3 Consumer Preferences and Choice

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

03-Salvatore-Chap03.qxd 08-08-2008 12:41 PM Page 81<br />

Theory of<br />

revealed<br />

preference The<br />

theory that<br />

postulates that a<br />

consumer’s<br />

indifference<br />

curve can be<br />

derived from the<br />

consumer’s<br />

market behavior.<br />

<strong>CHAPTER</strong> 3 <strong>Consumer</strong> <strong>Preferences</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Choice</strong> 81<br />

The fact that the marginal utility approach gives the same result as the indifference<br />

curve approach (i.e., 2X <strong>and</strong> 6Y) should not be surprising. In fact, we can easily show why<br />

this is so. By cross multiplication in equation [3.6], we get<br />

MUX<br />

MUY<br />

= PX<br />

PY<br />

[3.7]<br />

But we have shown in Section 3.2 that MRSXY = MUX/MUY (see equation [3.2]) <strong>and</strong> in<br />

Section 3.5 that MRSXY = PX/PY when the consumer maximizes utility (see equation<br />

[3.5]). Therefore, combining equations [3.2], [3.5], <strong>and</strong> [3.7], we can express the condition<br />

for consumer utility maximization as<br />

MRSXY = MUX<br />

MUY<br />

= PX<br />

PY<br />

[3.8]<br />

Thus, the condition for consumer utility maximization with the marginal utility approach<br />

(i.e., equation [3.6]) is equivalent to that with the indifference curve approach (equation [3.5]),<br />

except for corner solutions. With both approaches, the value of equation [3.8] is 2.<br />

AT THE FRONTIER<br />

The Theory of Revealed Preference<br />

U<br />

ntil now we have assumed that indifference curves are derived by asking the consumer<br />

to choose between various market baskets or combinations of commodities.<br />

Not only is this difficult <strong>and</strong> time consuming to do, but we also cannot be sure that<br />

consumers can or will provide trustworthy answers to direct questions about their preferences.<br />

According to the theory of revealed preference (developed by Paul Samuelson<br />

<strong>and</strong> John Hicks), a consumer’s indifference curves can be derived from observing the<br />

actual market behavior of the consumer <strong>and</strong> without any need to inquire directly about<br />

preferences. For example, if a consumer purchases basket A rather than basket B, even<br />

though A is not cheaper than B, we can infer that the consumer prefers A to B.<br />

The theory of revealed preference rests on the following assumptions:<br />

1. The tastes of the consumer do not change over the period of the analysis.<br />

2. The consumer’s tastes are consistent, so that if the consumer purchases basket<br />

A rather than basket B, the consumer will never prefer B to A.<br />

3. The consumer’s tastes are transitive, so that if the consumer prefers A to B<br />

<strong>and</strong> B to C, the consumer will prefer A to C.<br />

4. The consumer can be induced to purchase any basket of commodities if its<br />

price is lowered sufficiently.<br />

Figure 3.12 shows how a consumer’s indifference curve can be derived by<br />

revealed preference. Suppose that the consumer is observed to be at point A on budget<br />

line NN in the left panel. In this case, the consumer prefers A to any point on or below<br />

NN. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, points above <strong>and</strong> to the right of A are superior to A since they<br />

involve more of commodity X <strong>and</strong> commodity Y. Thus, the consumer’s indifference<br />

curve must be tangent to budget line NN at point A <strong>and</strong> be above NN everywhere else.<br />

Continued . . .

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!