08.08.2013 Views

Do consumer s tastes differ final 1.7. - HEC

Do consumer s tastes differ final 1.7. - HEC

Do consumer s tastes differ final 1.7. - HEC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

G.S. Becker: Accounting for Tastes 15<br />

D O C ONSUMER’ S T ASTES D IFFER?<br />

Becker (1998) introduces an approach, which includes “soft values” like leisure for example. As he is<br />

using a rather abstract approach, he does not really apply a concrete sample, but mainly refers to a<br />

household in an economy.<br />

Contrary to most other authors, Becker (1998) supposes that consumption behaviour has only little to<br />

do with basic biological needs for food, drink, shelter and some recreation. He highlights aspects like<br />

childhood and other experiences, social interaction, and cultural influences.<br />

His view reflects the aim to establish a link between two ways of discussing demand: economic or<br />

political and sociological or anthropological. The first often neglects the structure of preferences; the<br />

second does not use an efficient analytical approach.<br />

To allow a broader approach, Becker (1998) includes two new variables for analysing preferences:<br />

P: personal capital<br />

including the relevant past consumption and other personal experiences<br />

effecting current and future utilities<br />

S: social capital<br />

integrating the influence of past actions by peers and others in an<br />

individual’s social network and control system.<br />

The introduction of the above variables changes the utility function, as it not only depends on the<br />

goods consumed but also on the stock of personal and social capital at that moment. The utility<br />

function itself is time-independent, thus being a stable function over time of the goods consumed and<br />

of the capital stocks. As a consequence, the stability of the utility function is mainly due to the<br />

inclusion of past experiences and social influences.<br />

Hereby Becker (1998) has created a revised utility function, which enhances the power of stable<br />

preferences and utility maximisation as it significantly explains a wide range of behaviour. Utility does<br />

not directly depend on specific goods and <strong>consumer</strong> capital stocks, but on the household’s objects of<br />

choice, called commodities – such as health, social standing and reputation, and pleasures of the<br />

senses – produced by themselves. Consequently, the variables in this utility function do not purely<br />

consist of ordinary goods, but additionally of advertisements, education, and other determinants of<br />

preferences normally not considered as “goods“.<br />

Households will therefore maximise a utility function of commodities. These commodities that they<br />

produce themselves are not evaluated by the market price, but by a “shadow price”, the cost of<br />

production. These costs include the quantity of the market good used to produce the commodity, the<br />

person’s own time input, and other input-output coefficients. As these numerous and varied<br />

determinants describe the shadow price, prices do take subtle forms.<br />

Another <strong>differ</strong>ence to usual models is the definition of a household’s income. Contrary to other<br />

approaches, Becker does not use the real income which is the money income deflated by an index of<br />

the prices of market goods. Instead, he uses a household’s full income, representing the maximum<br />

money income it could achieve by an appropriate allocation of the given prices of commodities. As full<br />

income and commodities depend on various factors, a household’s income can take refined forms.<br />

When considering rich and poor, black and white, less and more educated persons, persons living in<br />

countries with totally <strong>differ</strong>ent traditions and their <strong>differ</strong>ent utility functions, Becker uses the approach<br />

that the <strong>differ</strong>ences are due to subutility functions which are not similar due to influences of childhood<br />

and other experiences. Their extended utility functions, however, are regarded as similar. In order to<br />

analyze and explain behaviour in a productive way, the extended utility functions are used in the<br />

model and are considered as stable.<br />

15 This section summarizes Becker, G.S., Accounting for <strong>tastes</strong>, Harvard University Press paperback edition, 1998<br />

B EKE T INNEBERG 12<br />

19 MARCH 2003

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!